United States Office of Air Quality FINAL REPORT Environmental Protection Planning and Standards EPA-452/R-96-012 Agency Research Triangle Park, NC 27711 September 1996 Air ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS OF THE PROPOSED NESHAP FOR FLEXIBLE POLYURETHANE FOAM Final Report ------- Economic Impact Analysis of the Proposed NESHAP for Flexible Polyurethane Foam U.S. Environmental Protection Agency Office of Air and Radiation Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards Air Quality Strategies and Standards Division MD-15; Research Triangle Park, N.C. 27711 Prepared by: Mathtech, Inc. 202 Carnegie Center, Suite 111 Princeton, N.J. under subcontract to: E.H. Pechan and Associates 5527 Hempstead Way Springfield, Va. Final Report September 1996 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ------- The U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) is developing National Emission Standards for Hazardous Air Pollutants (NESHAP) for new and existing producers of flexible polyurethane foam. The flexible polyurethane foam industry includes producers of flexible slabstock foam and flexible molded foam. Both slabstock and molded foam are used as intermediate products in a number of industries. The primary uses of flexible slabstock foam are in the furniture, automobile, carpet and bedding industries. Among the industries which use flexible molded foam are automobile, furniture, packaging, and textiles and fiber manufacturing. Both slabstock and molded foam producers emit hazardous air pollutants (HAPs)1 identified by the Clean Air Act Amendments of 1990. Accordingly, this Economic Impact Analysis (EIA) has been conducted to satisfy the requirements of the Clean Air Act (Section 317), and the Regulatory Flexibility Act. ANALYSIS OBJECTIVES The primary objective of this analysis is to describe the magnitude and distribution of adverse impacts associated with alternative NESHAPs among various members of society. This study estimates the costs to society and describes the adverse impacts associated with the alternative NESHAPs. Those members of society who could potentially suffer adverse impacts include: • Producers whose facilities require emission controls. • Buyers of goods produced by industries requiring controls. • Employees at plants requiring controls. • Individuals who could be affected indirectly such as residents of communities proximate to controlled facilities, and producers and 1 These HAPs are methylene chloride (MeCI2) and toluene diisocyanate (TDI). EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ES-2 ------- employees in industries that sell inputs to or purchase inputs from directly affected firms. BACKGROUND Affected Markets EPA expects the alternative NESHAPs to affect two sectors of the foam production industry included in Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) 3086. These are: • Producers of flexible polyurethane slabstock foam. • Producers of flexible polyurethane molded foam. Foam Chemistry and Production Polyurethane foams are made by adding water to a polyol/diisocyanate reaction mixture. During the reaction, C02 is formed and acts as a "blowing agent" by creating bubbles that expand and create a network of cells separated by thin membranes. The formation of the cells I n the foam determine the foam's properties, such as softness and durability. Because certain foam properties are limited when using CCb as the sole blowing agent, auxiliary blowing agents (ABAs) are often used. The ABAs vaporize due to the heat generated during the reaction and help the carbon dioxide expand the foam, and also reduces the heat formation from the isocyanate reaction (thus preventing scorching of the foam). Previously, the principal ABA used was chlorofluorocarbon 11 (CFC-11). However, since this compound has been shown to deplete the earth's ozone layer, U.S. producers have almost completely phased out its use. Methylene chloride (MeCb), a listed HAP, has replaced CFC-11 as the principal ABA. Since the role of the methylene chloride is simply to volatize and expand the EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ES-3 ------- foam, it does not directly participate in the polyurethane reaction. Therefore, all MeCI2 used in the reaction is eventually emitted. As mentioned previously, there are two types of foam production processes: slabstock and molded. While the chemistry and final products of slabstock and molded foam production are similar, the production processes, emission sources, and control techniques are very different. While molded foam is manufactured in a batch-type process, slabstock is produced using a continuous method. The major emission source for slabstock foam is from the use of ABAs, but there is no analogous emission point for molded foam production. The only significant HAP emission point that the two segments share is equipment cleaning. Generally, the reasons for emissions and available control technologies are quite different for the two industry segments. Regulatory Alternatives The Clean Air Act Amendments of 1990 stipulate that HAP emission standards for existing sources must at least match the percent reduction of HAPs achieved by either (a) the best 12 percent of existing sources, or (b) the best five sources in a cate- gory or subcategory consisting of fewer than 30 sources. This minimum standard is called a MACT Floor. Because of the technical differences in the flexible polyurethane foam production industry noted above, EPA has separated the industry into several subcategories. This analysis evaluates the molded foam production and slabstock foam production subcategories. For each of these subcategories, three regulatory alternatives have been analyzed. The first represents the maximum achievable control technology (MACT) "floor" level of control. This level of control is the minimum stringency for a NESHAP developed in accordance with section 112(d) of the Clean Air Act Amendments. Existing source regulatory alternatives that achieve greater emission reductions than the floor level were also developed for each of these subcategories (Regulatory Alternative 1 and Regulatory Alternative 2). EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ES-4 ------- There are currently seventy-eight (78) facilities producing flexible slabstock foam and approximately two-hundred-thirty-four (234) facilities producing molded foam. For both sectors, the MACT Floor for existing sources was constructed by averaging the emissions levels of the best 12 percent of existing sources. A source type is a piece of equipment or component of production which produces HAPs. The MACT Floor requires controls on HAP emissions from the following slabstock foam source types: • Production processes. • Storage/unloading processes. • Equipment cleaning. • Equipment leaks. Molded foam source types controlled by the MACT Floor are: • Mixhead cleaning, or "flushing." • Mold release agent usage. • The use of HAP-based adhesives to repair damaged foam. Table ES-1 shows the three existing source regulatory alternatives for slabstock foam. Regulatory Alternative 1 increases the stringency of the requirements for equipment leak and ABA usage emissions in that it requires a combination of equipment modifications and the execution of a leak detection and repair (LDAR) program to reduce equipment leak emissions. Alternative 1 also includes a lower allowable HAP ABA emission level. Regulatory Alternative 2 prohibits HAP ABA emissions. This would, in effect, prohibit the usage of any MeCb as an ABA. Since no HAP ABA would be allowed, there is no need for HAP ABA storage or equipment leak requirements. Table ES-2 shows the three existing source regulatory alternatives for molded foam production by source and type of control. Since the MACT Floor prohibits the use EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ES-5 ------- of HAP-based mold release agents and adhesives, the only emission source with the potential for more stringent requirements is mixhead flushing. Regulatory Alternative 1 requires work practices to reduce mixhead flushing emissions and Regulatory Alternative 2 prohibits the use of HAP-based mixhead flushes. Table ES-1 REGULATORY ALTERNATIVES FOR SLABSTOCK FOAM EXISTING SOURCES Reg. Alt. MACT Floor 1 2 Storage/ Unloading HAP ABA & TDI- vapor balance/carbon HAP ABA & TDI- vapor balance/carbon TDI- vapor balance/carbon Components in HAP Service Leakless TDI pumps Leakless TDI pumps Unique LDAR Leakless TDI pumps Equipment Cleaning HAP prohibition HAP prohibition HAP prohibition HAP ABA Emissions Existing HAP ABA emission limit Intermediate HAP ABA emission limit HAP prohibition Source: EC/R Incorporated (1996a). Table ES-2 REGULATORY ALTERNATIVES FOR MOLDED FOAM EXISTING SOURCES Regulatory Alternative MACT Floor 1 2 Mixhead Flush No control Work practice HAP prohibition Mold Release Agents HAP prohibition HAP prohibition HAP prohibition Repair Adhesive HAP prohibition HAP prohibition HAP prohibition Source: EC/R Incorporated (1996a). SUMMARY OF ESTIMATED IMPACTS Primary and Secondary Impacts EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ES-6 ------- Table ES-3 summarizes the estimates of the primary and secondary economic impacts associated with the MACT Floor and the two additional regulatory alternatives. Primary impacts include price increases, reductions in market output levels, changes in the value of shipments by domestic producers, and plant closures. Note that for the slabstock sector, we report a range of plant closures based on a sensitivity analysis of emission control technologies (found in Appendix D). Secondary impacts include em- ployment losses, reduced energy use, changes in net exports, and potential regional impacts. Table ES-3 SUMMARY OF ESTIMATED ECONOMIC IMPACTS Analysis Estimated Impacts Primary Impacts Price Increases Market Output Value of Domestic Shipments Plant Closures Estimated price increases range from 2.20 to 3.82 percent for the slabstock segment and from 0.07 to 1.14 percent for the molded foam segment of the industry under the three regulatory alternatives. Estimated reductions in market output range from 1 .08 to 1 .86 percent for slabstock foam and from 0.04 to 0.56 percent for molded foam. Increases in the value of domestic shipments range from 1 .1 0 to 1 .89 percent for slabstock foam and from 0.04 to 0.57 percent for molded foam. For the slabstock foam market segment, predicted closures range from one to two under the MACT Floor, one to three under Regulatory Alternative 1 , and one to four under Regulatory Alternative 2. Predicted molded foam plant closures are zero under the MACT Floor, three under Regulatory Alternative 1 , and zero under Regulatory Alternative 2. These predicted closures are due in part to worst-case assumptions adopted in the analyses. Secondary Impacts Employment Energy Use Net Exports Regional Impacts Under the three regulatory scenarios, employment losses are estimated to range from 1 .08 to 1 .86 percent (95 to 164 jobs) in the slabstock segment and 0.04 to 0.56 percent (2 to 31 jobs) in the molded segment. Estimated industry-wide energy use to decline by 1 .08 to 1 .86 percent ($409.6 to $703.0 thousand) in the slabstock industry and by 0.04 to 0.56 percent ($8.9 to $133.5 thousand) in the molded industry. No significant trade impacts are expected. No significant regional impacts are expected. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ES-7 ------- The market price for slabstock foam is estimated to increase by 2.28 percent ($0.03/lb) under the MACT Floor, 2.20 percent ($0.03/lb) under Regulatory Alternative 1, and 3.82 percent ($0.05/lb) under Regulatory Alternative 2. Corresponding decreases in market output are estimated as: 1.12 percent under the MACT Floor, 1.08 percent under Regulatory Alternative 1, and 1.86 percent under Regulatory Alternative 2. The estimated impacts of the MACT Floor on price and output in the molded foam sector are smaller than those predicted for the slabstock market. For the molded foam industry, we estimate an increase in price of only 0.07 percent ($0.0017/lb) under the MACT Floor, 0.84 percent ($0.02/lb) under Regulatory Alternative 1, and 1.14 percent ($0.03/lb) under Regulatory Alternative 2. Corresponding decreases in market output are estimated as: 0.04 percent under the MACT Floor, 0.42 percent under Regulatory Alternative 1, and 0.56 percent under Regulatory Alternative 2. Note, however, that we expect increases in the value of shipments by both domestic slabstock and molded foam producers under all regulatory alternatives. This occurs because estimated price increases more than offset the lower production volumes. The value of shipments of slabstock foam are estimated to increase by 1.14 percent ($19.53 million) under the MACT Floor, 1.10 percent ($18.82 million) under Regulatory Alternative 1, and 1.89 percent ($32.56 million) under Regulatory Alternative 2. The value of shipments of molded foam is estimated to increase by 0.04 percent ($0.391 million) under the MACT Floor, 0.42 percent ($4.50 million) under Alternative 1, and 0.57 percent ($6.10 million) under Alternative 2. For the slabstock foam industry, the analysis predicts one to two plant closures under the MACT Floor, one to three plant closures under Regulatory Alternative 1 and one to four plant closures under Regulatory Alternative 2. These predicted closures, however, are due in part to some of the "worst-case" assumptions adopted in the analysis.2 2 For example, we assume that plants with the highest emission control costs are the least efficient producers in the market. Also, our analysis does not consider that some plants are protected by regional EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ES-8 ------- For the molded foam industry, the analysis predicts no plant closures under the MACT Floor, three plant closures under Regulatory Alternative 1, and no plant closures under Regulatory Alternative 2. Again, these predicted closures are due in part to the worst-case assumptions adopted in the analysis. trade barriers. Actual plant closures will be fewer than predicted closures if plants with high emission control costs are not the least efficient producers or if these plants are protected by regional trade barriers. We also note that predicted plant closures are sensitive to assignments of emission control technologies (see Appendix D). EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ES-9 ------- The estimates of slabstock sector secondary impacts reported in Table ES-3 are consistent with the primary impacts estimates described above. We estimate reductions in employment and energy use of 1.12 percent under the MACT Floor, 1.08 percent under Regulatory Alternative 1, and 1.86 percent under Regulatory Alternative 2.3 Since no significant export or import markets for slabstock foam exist, no significant trade impacts are expected. The secondary impacts on the molded foam industry are less than those for the slabstock segment. Reductions in employment and energy use are estimated to be only 0.04 percent under the MACT Floor, 0.42 percent under Regulatory Alternative 1, and 0.56 percent under Regulatory Alternative 2. As with slabstock foam, no significant export or import markets for molded foam exist; accordingly, no significant trade impacts are expected. Financial Analysis The analysis of financial data for a sample of firms indicates that capital and annual emission control costs are small relative to the financial resources of the firms producing flexible polyurethane slabstock and molded foam. As a result, we do not find evidence that it will be difficult for these firms to raise the capital required to purchase and install emission controls. We note, however, that data in not available for most privately owned companies. The producers for which financial data are available tend to be larger publicly held companies. As a result, these firms might not be representative of all producers in the industry. Sensitivity Analyses 3 As was the case for predicted plant closures, our estimates of employment and energy impacts are due in part to the worst-case assumptions adopted in our analysis. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ES-10 ------- Appendix C examines the sensitivity of the estimated primary impacts to alternative assumptions about market demand and supply elasticities. The results reported in Appendix C indicate that the primary impacts summarized in Table ES-3 are relatively insensitive to reasonable ranges of elasticities. Appendix D examines the sensitivity of the counts of predicted plant closures to the assignment of compliance technologies for the slabstock industry segment. Given that there exist multiple technologies (of different costs) which will bring a source type into compliance with a regulatory scenario, altering the assignment of compliance technologies to model plants affects the estimated impacts of the regulatory scenario. Impacts can be reduced by assuming that more plants will opt for lower-cost emission control technologies. Potential Small Business Impacts The Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA) requires an analysis of potential impacts on small entities, which are defined by the employment or sales level of the parent company that owns a facility. Due to insufficient data on the ownership of numerous plants in the flexible polyurethane foam industry, an analysis of each parent company in the industry is not feasible. Alternatively, data collected in the section 114 survey is used to evaluate the impact on small flexible foam businesses based on model facilities. The Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (IRFA) indicates that there are a total of 71 small businesses (18 slabstock, 53 molded) that are affected by the regulatory alternatives. For the molded foam sector, the IRFA indicates that the smallest model plant does not incur any compliance costs, and the average change in operating costs as a percentage of revenues for all other model plant sizes is less than one percent. This impact is not considered to be significant to affected small businesses. In addition, the economic analysis does not indicate any closures of molded foam facilities as a result of EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ES-11 ------- the MACT floor and Regulatory Alternative 2, however, Regulatory Alternative 1 indicates 3 closures of the mid-sized model plant (LP2). For the slabstock sector, the average change in operating costs as a percent of revenues at the smallest model plant is 1.59 percent for the MACT floor, 1.84 percent for Regulatory Alternative 1, and 2.29 for Regulatory Alternative 2. For all other model plant sizes, this value is equal to or less than one percent. The economic analysis estimates a range of closures for each slabstock model plant size. The smallest model plant is estimated to have between 0 and 2 closures for the MACT floor, and between 0 and 3 closures for Regulatory Alternatives 1 and 2. The next largest model plant is estimated to have between 0 and 1 closure for all regulatory alternatives. Because there is insufficient data to determine the exact ownership of the plants that may close, the analysis cannot determine if these impacts will occur at small businesses. Given that any estimate of closures is based upon worst-case assumptions, it is likely that these impacts are overestimated and the affect on small businesses will be minimal. Social Costs and Economic Efficiency Table ES-4 reports estimates of the social (economic) costs associated with the alternative NESHAPs for the slabstock and molded foam segments of the industry. We measure social costs as changes in economic surplus resulting from compliance costs.4 The total estimated annualized social costs for the slabstock and molded subcategories combined range from $7.24 million (Regulatory Alternative 1) to $12.05 million (MACT Floor). The estimates of emission reductions reported in Table ES-4 include lower emission reductions due to controls as well as adjustments for predicted plant closures. Specifically, we assume that emissions fall to zero at plants predicted to close. Because the proposed options choose Regulatory Alternative 1 for the slabstock subcategory and Regulatory Alternative 2 for the molded subcategory, this equates to a total social cost of the proposed rule to be $7.89 million. See Section 7 for a discussion of changes in economic surplus as a measure of social costs. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ES-12 ------- Table ES-4 SOCIAL COSTS AND ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY OF REGULATORY ALTERNATIVES Regulatory Alternative MACT Floor Regulatory Alternative 1 Regulatory Alternative 2 Annual Social Costs ($1994MM) Slabstock 11.86 7.18 10.92 Molded 0.19 0.06 0.71 Total 12.05 7.24 11.63 Annual Emission Reduction (tons) Slabstock 9 ,774 1 1,796 1 6,958 Molded 331 1,846 2,331 Total 10, 105 13, 642 19, 289 A regulatory alternative is economically efficient if it generates larger net benefits (benefits minus costs) than other alternatives. A dominant alternative generates the same or larger total emission reductions at a lower cost than any other alternative. Since we presume that larger emission reductions yield higher benefits, a dominant alternative is economically efficient relative to all other alternatives (since it produces the same or larger benefits at a lower cost). An inferior alternative, on the other hand, generates the same or smaller emission reductions at a higher cost than at least one other alternative. An inferior alternative is economically inefficient because at least one other alternative generates higher net benefits. As the results in Table ES-4 indicate, none of the three regulatory alternatives is clearly dominant. However, the MACT Floor is inferior to both Alternative 1 and EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ES-13 ------- Alternative 2. The MACT Floor generates lower annual emission reductions at higher annual costs than either Alternative 1 or Alternative 2. Therefore, we conclude that the MACT Floor is economically inefficient relative to these two regulatory alternatives. Note that Alternative 2 generates larger emission reductions than Alternative 1, but at higher costs. As a result, the information provided in Table ES-4 is not sufficient to evaluate the economic efficiency of Alternative 2 relative to Alternative 1. Alternative 2 would be efficient relative to Alternative 1 if the additional benefits associated with higher emission reductions (5,647 tons annually) exceed its incremental costs ($4.39 million annually). One final comment on why this analysis is worthwhile. Some of the estimated economic impacts associated with Alternatives 1 and 2 are more adverse than for the MACT Floor (e.g., more closures) even though the MACT Floor gives rise to higher social costs. This occurs because, compared with the MACT Floor, Alternatives 1 and 2 impose higher compliance costs on marginal (higher cost) plants, but more than offsetting lower costs on non-marginal plants. Thus, while the MACT Floor is inferior, some of its economic impacts are less severe than those for Alternatives 1 and 2. In other words, some of the distributional impacts of the MACT floor are less severe than those of the other regulatory alternatives. LIMITATIONS Several limitations of the analyses used to estimate the impacts of the alternative NESHAPs are described throughout this report. All of these limitations should be considered in interpreting the estimated impacts summarized above. In particular, many of the assumptions adopted in the analyses tend to cause the estimated adverse impacts associated with the alternative NESHAPs to be overstated. ORGANIZATION OF REPORT EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ES-14 ------- Section 1 of this report is an industry profile of the flexible polyurethane foam industry. In Section 2, we describe the model plants and report the estimated compliance costs used in the analyses. We describe the analytical methods employed to estimate the economic impacts associated with the alternative NESHAPs in Section 3. In Section 4, we report estimates of primary economic impacts, including those on market prices, market output levels, value of shipments by domestic producers, and plant closures. Section 5 presents estimates of secondary impacts, including the effects on employment, foreign trade, energy use and regional economies. We describe potential adverse impacts of small businesses in Section 6. In Section 7, we report estimates of the social costs and assess the economic efficiency of the alternative NESHAPs. There are four appendices to this report. We describe the model plants used in the analyses and report estimates of emission control costs and other baseline data in Appendix A. Appendix B provides a detailed technical description of the analytical methods employed to estimate economic impacts and costs. We report in Appendix C the results of sensitivity analyses in which we consider ranges of demand and supply elasticities. In Appendix D, we report the results of sensitivity analyses for the slabstock sector in which assumptions regarding the assignment of compliance technologies to model plants are modified. REFERENCE EC/R Incorporated (1996a). Technical memorandum from Phil Norwood and Amanda Williams to David Svendsgaard (EPA/OAQPS), January 26. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ES-15 ------- SECTION 1 INDUSTRY PROFILE INTRODUCTION The following is a profile of the industry segments affected by the Maximum Achievable Control Technology (MACT) standards for producers of flexible polyurethane foam. These are producers of flexible slabstock and flexible molded polyurethane foam. Both slabstock and molded foam producers emit hazardous air pollutants (HAPs) identified by the Clean Air Act Amendments of 1990. Information in this section is used to conduct analyses that are required by Section 317 of the Clean Air Act, which requires EPA to evaluate regulatory alternatives through an Economic Impact Analysis (EIA), and the Regulatory Flexibility Act, which requires an evaluation of the impacts on small entities. The objective of this section is to describe the markets for flexible polyurethane foams. Specifically, we: • Describe flexible polyurethane foam products and their uses, • Present data on foam prices and production levels, • Describe the market outlook for flexible polyurethane foam, • Characterize the industry's market structure, EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ES-16 ------- • Provide a brief description of the limited foreign trade in flexible polyurethanefoam, • Present financial data for foam producers, and • Present data on industry employment and energy use. PRODUCT DESCRIPTIONS Polyurethanes are made by reacting a polyol with a diisocyanate. The polyol is typically a polyester or a polyether with two or more -CH2OH functional groups. The diisocyanate is usually a mixture of a 2, 4- and 2, 6- isomers of toluene diisocyanate (TDI). Polyurethane foams are made by adding water to the reaction mixture. Surfactants and catalysts are also added to the mixture. The surfactants aid in mixing incompatible components of the reaction mixture, and also help control the size of the foam cells by stabilizing the forming gas bubbles. Catalysts balance the isocyanate/water and isocyanate/polyol reactions, and assist in driving the polymerization reaction to completion. The C02 formed in this reaction acts as the "blowing agent" creating bubbles that expand. The bubbles eventually come into close contact, forming a network of cells separated by thin membranes. At full foam rise, the cell membranes are stretched to their limits and rupture, releasing the blowing agent and leaving open cells supported by polymer "struts." The more water added, and C02 formed, the more expanded the polymer network, and the lower the resultant foam density. However, the reaction of isocyanate with water is extremely exothermic. The addition of too much water can cause the foam to scorch or auto-ignite. Because certain foam properties are limited when using C02 as the sole blowing agent, auxiliary blowing agents (ABA's) are often used. The ABA's vaporize due to the SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-2 ------- heat generated during the reaction and help the carbon dioxide expand the foam. The ABA also reduces the heat formation from the isocyanate reaction. Previously, the principal ABA used was chlorofluorocarbon 11 (CFC-11). However, since this compound has been shown to deplete the earth's ozone layer, U.S. producers have almost completely phased out its use. Methylene chloride (MeCI2), a listed HAP, has replaced CFC-11 as the principal ABA. Since the role of the methylene chloride is simply to volatilize and expand the foam, it does not directly participate in the polyurethane reaction. Therefore, all methylene chloride used in the reaction is eventually emitted. Polyurethane products can be classified into two major categories: foams and non-foams. Non-foam polyurethanes are coatings, adhesives, sealants, and elastomers. Polyurethane foams are produced in rigid and flexible forms. The industry producing flexible polyurethane foams is separated into two distinct segments, flexible slabstock foam and flexible molded foam. Although the foam chemistry in these sectors of the industry is analogous, the equipment, emission sources, and control technologies are different. Molded foam is produced by pouring, or "shooting" the foam reaction mixture into a mold of the desired shape and size. Slabstock foam is produced as large "buns" on semi-continuous moving conveyors. These buns are then cut, glued, or otherwise fabricated into the desired sizes and shapes.5 Flexible Slabstock Foam Toluene diisocyanate (TDI) and polyether polyol are the predominant raw materials used to produce flexible slabstock foam. Catalysts, surfactants, blowing agents and other additives comprise the balance of materials used in the production process. The raw ingredients are pumped to a mixing head and discharged through 5 Fora further discussion of the technical processes involved in the manufacture of flexible polyurethane foam, see Schultz (1989) and EC/R Incorporated (1995). SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-3 ------- the nozzle onto the front of a conveyor belt (called the foam line) at a rate of between 400 and 1,000 pounds per minute. The conveyor first passes through an enclosed, ventilated tunnel, where the ingredients react quickly to form the foam bun. From the point of its maximum expansion, the foam begins to release blowing agents and unreacted chemicals. These chemicals are exhausted from the enclosed section. As the bun leaves the conveyor, it is sawed into sections and transported to a curing area, where the foam reaction continues to completion and the remainder of the blowing agents leave the bun. There are no standard dimensions for a slabstock bun. A typical bun can be 4 feet tall, 8 feet wide, and 50 to 100 feet long. However, buns can range from a width of 3 to 9 feet and may be up to hundreds of feet in length. Slabstock foam is produced on a need basis, generally to fill existing orders. The size of the facility, more than the speed of the foam line, acts as a constraint on how much foam can be produced. The foam line production process generally takes between 2 and 4 hours before the bun is ready for transport to the curing area. After the foam bun is transported to the curing area, it must sit untouched for between 24 and 48 hours before any fabrication, shipping, or movement to storage can occur. Foam production in smaller facilities is thus limited by the amount of space available for foam curing and in some cases storage (Peters, 1995). Figure 3-1 illustrates the most popular machinery used in the production of flexible polyurethane slabstock buns, the Maxfoam process. As the figure indicates, the mixing head is fixed and the liquid coming from the head is fed into the bottom of a trough where it begins to react. The reacting mass then flows over the forward edge of the trough and onto the bottom paper, which is sliding on an inclined fall-plate. The fall-plate is made up of five sections hinged together at pivot points. The angle of each fall-plate section can be changed by raising or lowering the height of the pivot points. By changing the configuration of the fall-plate sections, the rise of the foam can be controlled. The foam, which expands downward, reaches the horizontal conveyor as a fully expanded slab. When the fall-plate sections are properly adjusted, the reacting SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-4 ------- foaming mass flowing out of the trough will be evenly distributed between the sidewalls. The surface of the slab will follow the side paper on a horizontal line at the same level as the top of the foam expanding from the trough, thus producing a flat-topped block (Harrington and Hack, 1991). Prior to being delivered to the end-user, the large buns are fabricated according to their end-use. The simplest method of fabrication is to cut the foam into the desired shape and size. However, many customers require the gluing of foam-to-foam or foam to some other non-foam product. Figure 1-1. Maxfoam Process SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-5 ------- By altering the relative quantities of water, TDI, polyol, and auxiliary blowing agent used in the reaction, slabstock properties can be changed significantly. Foam properties and characteristics can be further altered by the addition of colorants, combustion modifiers, and fillers. The most important foam properties are density and Indentation Force Deflection (IFD). Foam is graded, or categorized, with two numbers, representing these proper- ties. The first, density, is measured in Ib/ft3 and is used to categorize slabstock into three general groupings as follows: • Foam with density less than 1.2 Ibs/ft3. • Foam with density between 1.2 Ibs/ft3 and 1.8 Ibs/ft3. • Foam with density greater than 1.8 Ibs/ft3 (Hull and Co., 1992). The second grading measure, the IFD, is a measure of foam stiffness (or softness). IFD is the amount of force (Ibs) it takes to push a 50 square inch disk down 25 percent of the total thickness of the foam. Density and IFD, although both measuring physical foam characteristics, are independent of one another. For example, a 1.0/30 foam is typically used in sofa arms and quilting. A 1.8/30 foam is considered quality sofa seat foam. These pieces differ in their density to correspond with their intended end use but are of the same softness. A foam with a given density can have any IFD value, just as foam with any IFD may be of any density. Desired density and IFD values are determined by the foam's application in the end-use market. As previously stated, IFD is a direct indicator of foam stiffness. However, density does not provide a direct measure of foam quality or durability. Generally, the higher the foam density, the higher the quality, but this is not always the case. Quality is often subjective to the end-use of the foam. Other foam properties and characteristics may provide a relative measure of "quality" unrelated to density. SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-6 ------- Some slabstock facilities also have rebond operations on-site. Rebond is the process by which scrap foam is ground up, placed in large molds and adhered together using an isocyanate (methylene chloride) and heat. This causes the small pieces to adhere and form a solid cylinder of foam. The cylinder is then peeled into sheets, which is primarily used as carpet underlay (carpet padding). Bonded carpet underlay is the major use for flexible polyurethane foam scrap. Because polyurethane foam producers are generally not in the business of producing scrap, the amount of material poured intentionally for bonded carpet underlay is limited by the amount of available storage space as much as it is by economic considerations. Intentional scrap is often made by using off-spec materials that would not be acceptable for use in cushions or bedding material. Intentional scrap does not hold together well and is used as an extender. Therefore, generally no more than 50 percent of the material used in a batch of rebond carpet underlay can be intentionally poured scrap. Flexible Molded Foam Although the basic polyurethane foam reaction is the same, molded foam production uses somewhat different chemical formulations from those used in slabstock production. These foams have higher densities than flexible slabstock foams, and therefore, seldom use an auxiliary blowing agent. In contrast to the slabstock process, the molding method is an intermittent batch process where the raw ingredients are shot into a mold and allowed to react. Unlike slabstock foam, where cutting and fabrication is necessary for the creation of the final foam product, the result of the molded foam production process is the final or intermediate product. Flexible molded foams are categorized into three classes in accordance with variance in their properties: • High resiliency (HR) • Semi-flexible SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-7 ------- • Hot molded. A typical foam molding line will consist of many functional parts. The majority of floor space will be taken up by conveying systems for the molds, ovens and related finished-foam handling systems. Conveyors for moving the foam molds from station to station can be of any number of layouts. Long racetrack-style designs are still as common as the newer, smaller, and more specialized carousel lines similar to that shown in Figure 3-2. In most cases, the mold moves under the mixing head where it received a charge of foam. It is SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-8 ------- Figure 1-2: Carousel Molding Line common to find the mixing head mounted on a robot or other computerized pour bridge for purposes of optimizing pour pattern for each individual mold cavity. After receiving the correct dose of foam, the mold is moved to a curing/storage area where the reaction continues to completion and the product is ready for delivery (Harrington and Hack, 1991). END-USE MARKETS Flexible slabstock and molded foams have a myriad of uses in six primary markets. These markets, which are described below, are: • Furniture • Transportation • Carpet • Bedding • Packaging SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-9 ------- • Textiles and Fibers. Table 1-1 shows the 1991 distribution of slabstock foam to end-use markets. As this table indicates, the major uses of slabstock foam include the manufacture of furniture, vehicles, carpeting, and bedding. Table 1-2 shows the major uses of molded flexible polyurethane foam. About 86 percent of molded foam is used in the manufacture of vehicles. Table 1-1 END-USE MARKET CONSUMPTION OF FLEXIBLE SLABSTOCK FOAM (1991) INDUSTRY SEGMENT Furniture Transportation Carpet* Bedding Packaging Textiles and Fibers Other Total CONSUMPTION (million Ibs.) 560 117 340 161 36 22 29 1,265 % TOTAL 44 9 27 13 3 2 2 100 * Carpet includes poured scrap and binder adhesives Source: Hull & Co., End-Use Market Survey on the Polyurethane Industry in the U.S. and Canada, 1992. SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-10 ------- Table 1-2 END-USE MARKET CONSUMPTION OF FLEXIBLE MOLDED FOAM (1991) INDUSTRY SEGMENT Transportation Auto Non-auto Furniture Packaging Textiles & Fibers Bedding Other Total CONSUMPTION (million Ibs.) 213 76 24 12 5 4 5 339 % TOTAL 63 23 7 4 1 1 1 100 Source: Hull & Co., End-Use Market Survey on the Polyurethane Industry in the U.S. and Canada, 1992. Transportation Uses in transportation include automobiles and light trucks, recreational vehicles, trucks, trailers, and railroad and aerospace applications. Cushions, shock-absorbent pads, and seating surfaces account for approximately 30 percent of total flexible foam production, and represent 80 percent of the flexible foam used in automotive applications. Typical automotive uses for flexible polyurethane foam are for such items as seat cushions, seat backs, headrests, arm rests, headliners, and under carpet sound insulation. Most of the parts are produced by molding rather than fabricating pieces cut from slabstock. In 1991, total production of flexible polyurethane molded foam products for the U.S. transportation industry was reported at 289 million pounds. Table 1-3 shows molded foam usage in a typical automobile. SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-11 ------- Table 1-3 MOLDED FOAM CONSUMPTION PER AUTOMOBILE APPLICATION Seating Instrument Panels Head Rests Arm Rests Consoles Carpets (molded) Other Total CONSUMPTION PER VEHICLE (pounds) 25.5 3.2 0.8 1.2 0.3 0.5 0.5 32.0 Source: Hull & Co., End-Use Market Survey on the Polyurethane Industry in the U.S. and Canada, 1992. Furniture Furniture is the largest end use of flexible polyurethane foam. In 1991, 584 million pounds, or 36 percent of total flexible foam produced, was used in the furniture industry, mainly for cushions, pillows, and padding. Table 1-7 describes the distribution of slabstock foam densities used in the furniture industry. The density and IFD chosen will vary with the desired properties of the furniture. Fabrication processes used in the manufacture of furniture generates a considerable amount of scrap during the conversion of slabstock to finished products. This scrap goes through "rebond" treatment and is used in the production of other flexible foam products, especially carpet underlay. The furniture market is primarily served by six large companies.6 ! This information is provided by Hull & Co. (1992). The six companies were not identified. SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-12 ------- Carpet Underlay In 1991, the U.S. market for carpet underlay used an estimated 570 million pounds of flexible polyurethane foam. Of this total, 119 million pounds represent virgin carpet underlay while 451 million pounds is bonded carpet underlay (rebond). Carpet underlay is produced by flexible slab foam producers and by stand-alone carpet underlay producers. Approximately 52 plants, located in 26 states, manufacture bonded carpet underlay in the U.S. (Hull & Co., 1992). In 1991, a total of 139 million pounds of virgin flexible slab foam was produced for carpet underlay applications. Of this quantity, 119 million pounds were used as produced and the remaining 20 million pounds were sent as scrap to bonded carpet underlay manufacturers. Table 1 -4 shows the foam components and quantities of each used in the 1991 production of bonded carpet underlay. Table 1-4 FOAM COMPONENTS OF BONDED CARPET UNDERLAY SCRAP SOURCE Flexible Foam Scrap Imported Foreign Scrap Binder Adhesives Molded Foam Scrap Post-Consumer Scrap Total Bonded Carpet Underlay Production MILLIONS OF POUNDS 251 133 40 17 10 451 Source: Hull & Co., End-Use Market Survey on the Polyurethane Industry in the U.S. and Canada, 1992. SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-13 ------- Bedding The bedding industry is the fourth largest user of flexible polyurethane foam, con- suming about 165 million pounds, or 5 percent of the total flexible foam produced. The bedding market consists of toppers and mattresses. Toppers are typically less than 1.5 inches thick and account for about 51 million pounds of foam, or 35 percent of bedding foam usage. Mattresses are 4 to 6 inches thick and use 94 million pounds of foam. Six or seven large companies share most of the market (Hull & Co., 1992). Packaging The packaging industry uses a wide range of polyurethane materials. In 1991, this industry used approximately 36 million pounds of flexible slab foam and 12 million pounds of molded foam. Polyurethane for packaging is limited by its higher cost relative to polystyrene. Flexible foams have important applications in packaging high cost speciality items as well as uses in interiors of carts for in-plant transport of speciality items. Textiles and Fibers In 1991, the textiles and fibers industry consumed approximately 27 million pounds of flexible foam. Apparel applications use flexible foam, mostly 1 -1.5 Ib / ft3 based on polyester polyol, melt-bonded onto fabric. Relatively small quantities of flexible foam are used as laminates to textile materials as backing. PRICES As previously discussed, flexible polyurethane slabstock foam is produced in large buns. The buns are sold to fabricators where they are cut and or glued to form SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-14 ------- foam of the desired shape and size for use in the end-use market. Prices paid by fabricators for slab foam varies with the grade (density) of the foam. They also vary somewhat with the geographic location of the end-use market. For example, foam to be used in California must adhere to stricter fire retardants and chemical use guidelines than the rest of the country (Bush, 1995). The necessary modifications to the production process results in higher production costs, and thus higher costs to the fabricators. Table 1-5 shows August 1995 median prices paid by fabricators for different grades of bulk slabstock foam. As this table indicates, higher density slabstock foam commands higher prices. Also, median California prices are moderately higher than prices for the rest of the domestic market. Molded foam prices vary depending on the amount of value added to the foam during the molding process. One industry source reports that molded foam prices in the range of $2.25 to $2.45 per pound are typical.7 Table 1-5 BULK SLABSTOCK FOAM PRICES Density (Ibs/ft3) 1.00 1.20 1.45 1.80 Price (per board foot) $0.125 $0.145 $0.165 $0.200 California Price (per board foot) $0.135 $0.170 $0.185 $0.225 Source: Bobby Bush Jr., Hickory Springs Manufacturing Company, telecom with Jeffrey Sassin, 8/30/95. 7 Jody Bevilaqua, Woodbridge Foam, telecom with Jeffrey Sassin, Mathtech, Inc., 3/15/96. SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-15 ------- OUTPUT From the period 1987 through 1994, production of flexible slabstock foam has increased over 35 percent, with annual increases during that span averaging about 4.6 percent (Peters, 1995) Decreases from previous year production levels occurred in 1990, and again in 1991.8 Since that time, industry production figures have been increasing, with the largest increase occurring from 1993 to 1994 (15.68 percent). In 1992, flexible molded foam production is estimated to have been approximately 339 million pounds, of which 58 percent was used in the automotive manufacturing industry (Hull & Co., 1992). Flexible slabstock production quantities and yearly trends are reported in Table 1 -6. As discussed earlier, slabstock foam is classified into one of three foam grades based upon its Ibs/ft3 density. Table 1-7 shows the distribution of slabstock foam, by foam grade, to end-use market. The data in this table are consistent with our earlier discussion that a variety of foam densities are often included in single end-use products. Because several different grades are produced at a facility throughout the year, it would be difficult to maintain control at specified emission limits for each foam grade. Therefore, the proposed MACT rule allows foam facilities to achieve compliance by averaging emissions across foam grades. Some foam grades require less ABA and therefore can meet emission limitations more easily than others. This raises the issue of whether compliance with the proposed rule will cause relatively larger adverse impacts in specific end-use markets. However, the data in Table 1-7 do not permit a straightforward answer to this question as the major end-use markets use a variety of foam densities. 8 The recession in 1990-91 caused a drop in production because the end-use markets for foam (i.e., automobiles, home furnishings, etc.) were severely affected by the slowed U.S. economy. SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-16 ------- Table 1-6 FLEXIBLE SLABSTOCK FOAM PRODUCTION YEAR 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 1987 PRODUCTION (billion Ibs) 1.512 1.307 1.237 1.168 1.247 1.250 1.187 1.117 % CHANGE 15.68 5.66 5.91 -6.34 -0.24 5.31 6.27 — Source: Lou Peters, Polyurethane Foam Association, telecom with Jeffrey Sassin, Mathtech, Inc. 8/8/95. SUBSTITUTES There are a limited number of products which serve as substitutes to flexible polyurethane foam. Primary among these are polyester fibers. Other products which may serve as substitutes to flexible foam are springs, rubber, and natural fibers. These products do not have the same properties as foam but in some cases may be applicable to similar uses. Table 1-7 1991 DISTRIBUTION OF FLEXIBLE SLAB FOAM TO END-USE MARKET BY FOAM GRADE Industry Segment <1.2 Ibs/ft3 1.2-1.8 Ibs/ft3 >1.8 Ibs/ft3 Total % Total SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-17 ------- Furniture Transportation Carpet* Bedding Packaging Textiles and Fibers Other Total 168 17 138 89 14 16 11 453 224 83 127 18 20 4 11 485 168 17 75 56 2 2 7 328 560 117 340 161 36 22 29 1,265 44 9 27 13 3 2 2 100 * Carpet includes poured scrap and binder adhesives Source: Hull & Co., End-Use Market Survey on the Polyurethane Industry in the U.S. and Canada, 1992. Since 1990, the use of polyester fiber as a substitute for flexible foams has been increasing. Among the end-use markets which may potentially be impacted by the substitution of polyester fiber for foam are the transportation, furniture, and bedding markets. In the furniture market, which accounts for approximately 44 percent of slabstock and 24 percent of molded foam consumption (see Tables 1-1 and 1-2), sheet and rolled polyester fiber is finding uses in furniture cushions, backs, and arms (McGovern, 1995). In the bedding market, which consumes almost 13 percent of U.S. slabstock production, polyester fiber can be substituted for foam in pillows, stuffing, mattress quilting, and fabric bulking for comforters. Differences in foam and fiber properties and characteristics influence decisions concerning which material to use. Reasons polyester fiber is chosen over flexible foam include: styling trends, its high filling capacity, surface softness, fabrication ease, and price. However, foam surpasses fiber when considering cushioning, recovery, durability, shape retention, and recyclability traits. SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-18 ------- Although trends in the bedding end-use market may be toward some fiber for foam substitution, bedding is the only major comfort application where full foam has yet to achieve its potential as the principal support material (Schultz, 1989). Despite the inherent advantages of the material, notably the availability of high quality grades, durability, comfort, and price, the innerspring industry has pre-empted competition in this multi-billion dollar market. A 1984 survey found that 78.1 percent of Americans still used a traditional innerspring mattress, and only 7.1 percent used foam mattresses. By contrast, nearly 50 percent of the bedding market in Europe is held by foam mattresses (Schultz, 1989). MARKET OUTLOOK The data presented earlier show that flexible polyurethane foam is used extensively in the manufacture of durable goods (e.g., vehicles and furniture). Since the demand for these goods tends to be highly cyclical, the derived demand for flexible polyurethane foam also tends to be cyclical, moving with the general economy. Flexible foam was hit hard by the recession of the early 1990's. The furniture and bedding market segments lost ground as consumers delayed making large purchases. However, the market recovered in 1992-1993 and flexible foam has bounced back. Unlike furniture and bedding, the carpet underlay market experienced stability during the 1991 recession when volume in this segment was down only slightly. This is a strong segment of the flexible foam market and should continue to see significant growth, particularly the rebond carpet underlay segment, which uses scrap generated from the automotive and furniture market (Friedrich, 1994). Although this application takes market share from prime underlay, it is a useful outlet for scrap and recycled foam. The growth in the transportation industry's use of flexible foam in 1992 can be expected to continue as long as car sales continue to rise. The 1993 model year was SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-19 ------- the best for passenger vehicles since 1989, with over 14 million cars, light trucks, and vans sold. More polyurethane is used in the automotive industry than any other plastic, and molded flexible foam seats and seatbacks are the largest application. A trend toward flatter seat cushions to save head space in compact cars should not affect polyurethane volume as cushions must be denser to offer the same comfort. Other uses of flexible polyurethane foam that should see incremental growth in the future include packaging, fabric laminates, weather stripping and household products. After the healthy growth in the polyurethane market in the mid 1980s, a slowdown in 1989 and a slump in 1990-1991, the future of the industry over the next decade is mixed. With traditional polyurethane foam markets such as furniture and automotive seat cushions at the saturation point, future growth is now more dependent on the economy than it has ever been before. Housing starts, commercial construction, consumer spending, and the domestic automotive industry will all help determine the growth in sales of flexible foams for the remainder of the decade. Nonetheless, some segments of the market are at an earlier point of the growth curve, and stronger gains can be expected in these areas. Here, new applications and systems technologies will continue to generate growth beyond incremental increases in the traditional segments. While the healthy growth of the mid 1980s may not return, modest increases in demand are expected for the remainder of the 1990s (Harrington, 1994). MARKET STRUCTURE Flexible foam products are large-volume, commodity products with little proprietary differentiation. Although certain companies have developed their own SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-20 ------- specialities in which they are pre-eminent (either in product application or geographic area), for the most part polyurethane foam produced by a manufacturer is interchangeable with that produced by any other manufacturer. Within the flexible polyurethane foam industry, vertical integration commonly exists from the raw materials market to foam production. Also, some vertical integration exists from foam production to end-product production. The flexible foam market in the United States totaled 1,604 million pounds in 1991, or approximately 51 percent of all polyurethanes produced. This total compares with a 1989 total of 1,735 pounds and represents an 8 percent drop in production across those years. Flexible slab foam production was 1,265 million pounds and accounted for 79 percent of this total. Flexible molded foam production was 339 million pounds, 21 percent of the total (Friedrich, 1994). Immediately below, we present data describing the horizontal structure of the flexible polyurethane industry. Next, we provide a brief qualitative description of the degree of vertical integration in the industry. Finally, we discuss industry demand and supply elasticities. HORIZONTAL MARKET STRUCTURE Flexible Slabstock Foam There are approximately seventy-eight facilities that produce slabstock flexible polyurethane foam in the United States. In 1992, the 10 largest firms accounted for almost 90 percent of industry-wide production of slabstock foam.9 Table 1 -8 shows the 10 largest slabstock producers in the United States, with the number of facilities each 9 Computed from Responses to the Industry Questionnaire 1993, issued under Section 114 of the CAAA. SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-21 ------- own, 1992 production and company market share. The remaining companies indi- vidually accounted for only small fractions of industry-wide output in 1992. However, because slabstock is a homogeneous, undifferentiated product, it is unlikely that any single producer commands significant market power. Slabstock is homogeneous in that foam with a given technical specification (e.g., density and IFD) can be viewed as a commodity. Table 1-8 LARGEST SLABSTOCK FOAM PRODUCERS (1992) COMPANY RANK 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Total FACILITIES OWNED 14 8 9 3 7 9 4 4 2 2 62 Production (1000 Ibs) 265,996 216,472 132,586 107,150 102,256 95,706 44,716 44,178 33,648 33,000 1,075,708 MARKET SHARE (%) 22.1 17.99 11.02 8.9 8.5 7.95 3.75 3.67 2.8 2.74 89.38 Source: Responses to the Industry Questionnaire 1993, issued under Section 114 of the CAAA. Due to the cost of shipping foam relative to its size and weight (typical slabstock foam weighs one to two Ibs/ft3), shipping cost considerations and end-use market location are important determinants in the location of foam production facilities. SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-22 ------- Production facilities are usually found within close proximity to their end-use market or fabrication operation. It is economically advantageous for foam producing companies to establish a number of smaller facilities in proximity to end-use markets, rather than establish a single larger plant and incur greater transportation costs (Bush, 1995). Because foam is large and bulky, yet light in weight, shipping costs are high relative to the value of the foam. The economically feasible shipping distance of foam is limited to about 300 miles.10 Table 1-9 shows the distribution of slabstock facilities by state. While these facilities are geographically dispersed, they tend to be clustered close to end-use markets (e.g., carpeting in California and furniture manufacturing in North Carolina). 10 EC/R Incorporated (1993). SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-23 ------- Table 1-9 DISTRIBUTION OF SLABSTOCK FACILITIES BY STATE State Arkansas California Delaware Florida Georgia Illinois Indiana Iowa Kansas Kentucky Maryland Massachusetts Number of Facilities 3 9 1 4 4 3 8 1 1 1 1 1 State Michigan Minnesota Mississippi New Jersey New Mexico North Carolina Ohio Oregon Tennessee Pennsylvania Texas Virginia Number of Facilities 2 1 8 2 1 7 2 1 6 3 5 1 Source: Responses to Industry Questionnaire 1993, issued under Section 114 of the CAAA. Flexible Molded Foam There are approximately 234 facilities in the United States that produce flexible polyurethane molded foam. As of the date of this report, estimates of production for some plants in this industry segment are unavailable. As a result, market shares of the largest producers cannot be computed. However, because of the large number of facilities in the industry and the largely homogeneous nature of the product, it is unlikely that any single molded foam producer enjoys significant market power. SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-24 ------- VERTICAL MARKET STRUCTURE As noted earlier, vertical integration from foam production to fabrication is fairly commonplace in the industry. For example, 57 of the 78 slabstock facilities (about 73 percent) report having fabrication operations at their plants.11 Also, vertical integration in the molded foam segment exists in that the molding process adds value to the foam. DEMAND AND SUPPLY ELASTICITIES Both demand and supply elasticities in markets affected by the alternative MACT standards will determine the ability of affected plants to pass through control costs to buyers. Other things being the same, highly elastic demand will be associated with relatively small post-control price increases and with relatively large reductions in post-control output. On the other hand, elastic supply will be associated with relatively large post-control price increases and relatively large output reductions. Unfortunately, we have not identified any previous studies that provide estimates of demand and supply elasticities. Also, the data required to econometrically derive estimates for this study are unavailable. Below, we provide a qualitative discussion of elasticities for the flexible polyurethane industry. Demand Elasticity Three factors are important determinants of the demand elasticities faced by firms operating in affected industries. These three factors are: • The elasticity of demand for end-use products. 11 Computed from Responses to the Industry Questionnaire 1993, issued under Section 114 of the CAAA. SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-25 ------- • The fraction of total end-use costs attributable to inputs provided by affected plants. • The potential for substitutability with other inputs. In general, the elasticities of demand for end-use and intermediate products are directly related; other things being the same, elastic (inelastic) demand for an end-use product is associated with elastic (inelastic) demand for the primary or intermediate product. The fraction of total end-use costs attributable to an intermediate product, on the other hand, is inversely related to its demand elasticity; for example, an intermediate input which accounts for only a small fraction of the total cost of producing an end-use product will, other things being the same, have relatively inelastic demand, in part because it will have little influence on the price of the end-use product. Finally, the demand for an intermediate product will tend to be relatively elastic if substitute inputs are available. Earlier, we described the end uses of flexible polyurethane foam. The demand for these end-use products probably ranges from unit elastic (i.e., a demand elasticity of -1.0) to moderately elastic. For example, two major uses of flexible polyurethane foam are the manufacture of automobiles and furniture. Several studies of the automobile market are consistent with a long-run demand elasticity ranging from -1.0 to -1.5.12 There have been fewer studies of the furniture market, but a recent study by Mathtech (1994) in support of the Wood Furniture MACT, reports an estimated demand elasticity for the household sector of the wood furniture market of -3.36. Flexible polyurethane foam probably constitutes a small fraction of the total cost of manufacturing most end-use products. This is clearly the case for automobiles and trucks. Based on the slabstock prices reported earlier, it is also no doubt true that the 12 This range is consistent with early estimates reported by Nerlove (1957) and Suits (1958) and more recent estimates reported by Gallasch (1984). SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-26 ------- polyurethane foam content of furniture is a small fraction of total costs in the furniture industry. Finally, flexible polyurethane foam is superior to its substitutes in a number of respects, including appearance, performance, durability and comfort. While some substitutes exist (e.g., polyester fibers, natural fibers and "springs" in furniture manufacturing), these mostly have inferior attributes relative to foam. Taken as a whole, the evidence suggests that the demand for flexible polyurethane foam is relatively inelastic. While the demand for some end-use products might be moderately elastic, polyurethane foam constitutes a small fraction of the total cost of producing most end-use products and close substitutes for foam are generally unavailable. SUPPLY ELASTICITY The marginal cost of providing additional output in the relevant range of produc- tion is the most important factor determining supply elasticity. If the marginal cost of incremental output is relatively constant, then supply will be relatively elastic. However, if marginal costs rise steeply, supply will be relatively inelastic. In the short run, incremental costs will be determined largely by the properties of the production process and the existence of excess capacity in the industry. Long-run incremental costs are determined primarily by the production costs associated with newly constructed facilities, and the opportunity costs associated with investments in existing facilities. Unfortunately, our ability to characterize supply elasticity in the industry is somewhat limited. We do know that the national market is served by a large number of relatively small plants. This suggests the absence of significant scale economies in production and that supply is relatively elastic, at least in the long run (i.e., output can be added or deleted at about the same costs by constructing additional plants or closing SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-27 ------- existing plants).13 We caution, however, that the observed structure of the industry (i.e., a large number of geographically dispersed plants) represents a trade-off between scale economies in production and economizing on transportation costs (i.e., even if production economies exist, they could be outweighed by transportation costs associated with shipping greater distances). FOREIGN TRADE Given the nature of the product, foreign trade in flexible polyurethane foam is negligible. It is a large volume product with very little cost (value) per weight. Shipping a cargo of foam is quite similar to shipping 'air'. High transportation costs relative to foam value makes long distance foam transport uneconomical. However, some international trade in flexible polyurethane foam exists in the form of end-use products (e.g., in automobiles). Imports Although there is no import market for flexible slabstock or molded foam, there is a market for imports of flexible foam scrap for use in the rebond process. Foam scrap is primarily imported in the form of slabstock scrap but does include a small amount of molded scrap. In 1991, an estimated 133 million pounds of scrap foam was imported from abroad. Approximately 60 percent of this total was imported by three large brokers. The balance was imported directly by five large bonded carpet underlay manufacturers.14 13 Ignoring transportation costs, significant scale economies in production would result in a small number of relatively large facilities serving the national market. 14 This information is provided by Hull & Co. The five companies were not identified. SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-28 ------- Imported scrap competes with intentionally poured scrap. The quantity of scrap that is imported varies from year to year, depending on relative economics. During the first quarter of 1991, the price of imported scrap foam ranged from $0.45 to $0.60 per pound. By comparison, "intentional scrap" ranged from $0.58 to $0.70 cents per pound. The estimated volume of scrap imported to the United States in recent years is shown in Table 1-10. Table 1-10 ESTIMATED U.S. IMPORTS OF FLEXIBLE POLYURETHANE SCRAP Year 1991 1990 1989 1988 1987 Million Pounds 133 96 134 80 74 Source: Hull & Co., End-Use Market Survey on the Polyurethane Industry in the U.S. and Canada, 1992. Exports Due to the nature of the product, there are no exports of domestically produced flexible polyurethane foam to areas outside of the United States. As noted earlier, the typical weight of flexible foam ranges from 1 to 2 Ibs/ft3, and shipping costs are prohibitive. The flexible polyurethane foam industries in other countries produce foam to satisfy domestic demand. FINANCIAL DATA FOR FLEXIBLE POLYURETHANE FOAM FIRMS SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-29 ------- Financial data are needed to analyze the impact of the proposed regulations on firm profitability and to provide insight regarding firms' abilities to raise capital to finance the investment in emission control equipment. Immediately below, we present publicly available financial data for SIC 3086. We caution, however, that SIC 3086 includes other foam producers (e.g., rigid foam) in addition to flexible polyurethane foam. After the industry data are presented, we report available firm-specific financial data. Note that all financial data are reported at the firm level and therefore do not isolate the contribution of foam production to a company's financial status.15 SIC 3086 FINANCIAL DATA Financial data are available from Dun and Bradstreet, Inc. (D&B) and Robert Morris Associates (RMA) for the affected industry, SIC code 3086 — Plastics Foam Products. D&B and RMA present industry sector financial ratios that can be used to characterize the baseline (pre-regulatory) profitability and capital availability of firms in the affected industry. Both D&B and RMA compile profitability ratios for a sample of firms in the industry, and each of these ratios are then independently ranked from "most healthy" to "least healthy." The ratio that falls in the middle of the values represents the median ratio, those that occur mid-way between that median and the least healthy represent the lower quartile ratios, and those that fall mid-way between the median and the most healthy represent the upper quartile. This methodology is expected to adequately approximate the financial values of average firms in three relative states of financial health. This ranking is not available for the capital availability measure — only the average industry long term-debt to long-term debt plus equity ratio is available from both of these sources. 15 We note that firm-level financial data do not pose an issue for conducting a financial analysis of the impacts of the proposed MACT rule in the EIA. The purpose of this analysis is to assess the ability of affected firms to raise the capital required to finance investments required to achieve compliance with the proposed MACT rule. The financial resources available to the firm (not the foam facility) will determine the ability to raise capital. SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-30 ------- RMA also presents financial ratios by company sales and company asset ranges. However, only a portion of the applicable sales/asset ranges that are listed for the affected SIC code are displayed because RMA only presents data for sales/asset ranges with 10 or more financial statements. Table 1-11 presents both the overall financial ratios calculated using all of the financial data, and the ratios for the available individual size ranges. As with the D & B data, lower quartile, median, and upper quartile ratios are presented for profitability. To reduce the effect of business cycles and short-term perturbations, the profitability ratios are averaged over the 1991-1993 period (or 1992-1993 for RMA because data for SIC code 3086 were not available before 1991). Because changes in the long-term debt ratio represent actual structural changes, 1993 data are presented. The Society of the Plastics Industry, Inc. (SPI) publishes financial data for plastic product firms in different size ranges. However, these ratios are for the overall plastic products industry, and are not specific to the industry subject to the regulation (i.e., ratios are based on data for SIC code 308, and not SIC code 3086). Table 1-12 presents the profitability and capital availability information from the SPI. FIRM-SPECIFIC DATA Table 1-13 reports financial data (the ratio of net income to assets, long-term debt to long-term debt plus equity ratios and sales) for 35 firms producing flexible polyurethane foam. We report sales data in Table 1-13 for firms for which data on the financial ratios are unavailable. Comparable firm-specific financial and sales data for other firms in the industry are not publicly available.16 We caution that the firm-specific data reported in Table 1-13 might not be representative of all firms in the flexible 16 A total of 57 firms report producing flexible polyurethane foam in Responses to Industry Questionnaire 1993, issued under Section 114 of the CAAA. However, we understand that the survey does not capture all molded foam facilities. Accordingly, the survey count of 57 firms might understate the industry total. SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-31 ------- polyurethane foam industry. Specifically, financial data are more likely to be available for publicly-held firms which may have greater financial resources than firms that are not publicly held. SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-32 ------- Table 1-11 PROFITABILITY AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY MEASURES FOR SIC CODE 3086 PLASTICS FOAM PRODUCTS FINANCIAL MEASURE Profitability (% Net Income to Assets)2 Capital Availability (% Long-term Debt to Long-term Debt + Equity) FINANCIAL CONDITION Lower Upper Median/ Average Average SALES RANGE (in millions) All $0-1 $1-3 $3-5 $5-10 $1 0-25 $25+ All $0-1 $1-3 $3-5 $5-10 $1 0-25 $25+ All $0-1 $1-3 $3-5 $5-10 $1 0-25 $25+ All $0-1 $1-3 $3-5 $5-10 $1 0-25 $25+ Dun & Bradstreet 1991 2.9 20.2 9.0 NA 1992 0.2 23.0 4.0 NA 1993 1.6 13.6 7.1 19.4 •91 -'93 Averag e 1.6 18.9 6.7 NA Robert Morris Associates1 1992 2.4 n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a 7.9 15.4 n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a 12.3 8.7 n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a 18.8 NA 1993 3.3 n/a -0.3 1.8 2.1 n/a 6.8 16.9 n/a 5.2 6.4 5.9 n/a 12.8 9.3 n/a 10.9 15.3 11.2 n/a 17.1 16.8 n/a 25.1 17.1 14.4 n/a 15.3 '92 -'93 Average 2.9 n/a -0.3 1.8 2.1 n/a 7.4 16.2 n/a 5.2 6.4 5.9 n/a 12.6 9.0 n/a 10.9 15.3 11.2 n/a 18.0 NA Notes: 1Pre-1992 data for SIC code 3086 are not available from this source. 2For Robert Morris Associates, profit before taxes to total assets. n/a - not available. NA- not applicable. Sources: Dun and Bradstreet, Inc. Industry Norms and Key Business Ratios, 1992, 1993, and 1994; Robert Morris Associates, Annual Statement Studies, 1992 and 1993. SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-33 ------- Table 1-12 PROFITABILITY AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY MEASURES FOR PLASTIC PRODUCTS PRODUCERS, 1991 FINANCIAL MEASURE Profitability (% Return on Assets before Taxes) Capital Availability (% Long-term Debt to Long-term Debt + Equity) ALL 6.4 8.4 BY SALES VOLUME < $5 million 5.8 10.1 $5-$ 10 million 1.4 10.1 $10-25 million 11.2 5.6 > $25 million 4.1 8.7 Sources: The Society of the Plastics Industry, Inc., Financial and Operating Ratios, Survey No. 30, Plastic Processing Companies, July 1992. Table 1-13 FIRM-SPECIFIC FINANCIAL INFORMATION FOR FLEXIBLE POLYURETHANE FOAM INDUSTRY FIRM Company 1 Company 2 Company 3 Company 4 Company 5 Company 6 Company 7 Company 8 Company 9 Company 10 Company 11 Company 12 Company 13 Company 14 Company 15 Company 16 % NET INCOME TO ASSETS (averaged over 1991 -1993) 2.57 -1.37 2.23 -0.65 2.22 4.02 6.79 % 1993 LONG-TERM DEBT TO LONG-TERM DEBT + EQUITY 13.41 19.41 11.21 23.56 21.40 15.53 15.17 SALES (in $millions) 257.0 400.0 27.5 23.1 30.0 5.7 30.7 128.0 3.4 SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-34 ------- FIRM Company 17 Company 18 Company 19 Company 20 Company 21 Company 22 Company 23 Company 24 Company 25 Company 26 Company 27 Company 28 Company 29 Company 30 Company 31 Company 32 Company 33 Company 34 Company 35 % NET INCOME TO ASSETS (averaged over 1991 -1993) 4.49 -1.17 12.93 7.78 5.52 1.43 -0.87 % 1993 LONG-TERM DEBT TO LONG-TERM DEBT + EQUITY 26.32 11.13 21.70 10.59 31.84 42.22 9.99 SALES (in $millions) 14.6 6.9 585.0 200.0 155.0 68.5 20.0 50.0 22.1 32.9 40.0 108.0 Notes: a Net income assets ratio represents 1992-1993 only (1991 data were unavailable). b Net income assets ratio represents 1989-1991 (later data were unavailable). Sources: Moody's Industrial Manual, 1994; Moody's OTC Industrial Manual, 1994; Moody's OTC Unlisted Manual, Dun & Bradstreet's Million Dollar Directory, 1994; Herman Miller Annual Reports, 1989-1991. EMPLOYMENT The production of flexible polyurethane foam industry is non-labor intensive. Both large and small facilities need only a small number of specially trained employees to operate the foam production line. Foam production is, for the most part, an automated process requiring only monitoring once the proper mix of chemicals is SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-35 ------- completed and the production process is underway.17 Table 1-14 and 1-15 give employment figures for the plastic foam industry (SIC 3086), of which the flexible polyurethane foam industry is a subset. Due to data limitations, figures for the broader plastic foam industry were used as a proxy for the flexible polyurethane foam industry. Table 1-14 EMPLOYMENT STATISTICS (SIC 3086) Year 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 1987 Total Employees (1,000) 66.9 62 63.7 64.3 63.9 61.3 Production Workers (1,000) 52.3 47.8 49.6 48.8 50 47.7 Hours (millions) 100.5 92.1 95.6 92.4 97.5 91.8 Wages (million $) 1053.9 924.1 932.3 858.0 854.6 782.9 Payroll per Employee $23,735 $23,090 $21,911 $20,347 $19,892 $19,315 Source: 1992 Census of Manufactures, U.S. Department of Commerce Table 1-15 VALUE OF SHIPMENTS AND VALUE-ADDED PER LABOR HOUR (SIC 3086) Year 1992 1991 1990 Value of Shipments (million $) 9,488.4 8,578.0 8,988.2 Value Added by Manufacture (million $) 4,335.8 3,790.5 3,788.3 Value of Shipments per Production Worker Hour ($) 94.41 93.14 94.02 Value Added per Production Worker Hour ($) 43.14 41.16 39.63 17 While foam production is not labor intensive, foam fabrication is. This is an issue because the proposed MACT rule could indirectly affect fabrication operations through its impacts on foam production. SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-36 ------- 1989 1988 1987 8,108.9 7,506.5 6,912.8 3,271.0 3,290.3 3,045.6 87.76 76.99 75.30 35.40 33.75 33.18 Source: 1992 Census of Manufactures, U.S. Department of Commerce ENERGY USE As with employment data, disaggregate fuel and energy use data were not available beyond the four-digit SIC level. Tables 3-16 and 3-17 report 1992 consumption of fuels and electricity for SIC 3086 (Plastic Foams) for the industry and average facility, respectively. Table 1-16 INDUSTRY ENERGY USE (SIC 3086) Energy Source Fuels Purchased Electrici- ty Value (million $) 61.2 146.6 Quantity (million kWh) — 2,475.7 Source: 1992 Census of Manufactures, U.S. Department of Commerce Table 1-17 AVERAGE FACILITY ENERGY USE (SIC 3086) Energy Source Fuels Purchased Elec- Value ($) 50,288 120,460 Quantity (million kWh) — 2.034 SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-37 ------- I! tricity | Source: 1992 Census of Manufactures, U.S. Department of Commerce REFERENCES Bevilaqua, Jody (1996). Woodbridge Foam. Telecom with Jeffrey Sassin, Mathtech, Inc., 3/15/96. Bush, Bob Jr. (1995). Hickory Springs Manufacturing Company. Telecom with Jeffrey Sassin, Mathtech, Inc., 8/30/95. Dun and Bradstreet, Inc. Industry Norms and Key Business Ratios, 1992, 1992, 1994. EC/R Incorporated (1995). Technical Memorandum from Amanda Williams and Phil Norwood to David Svendsgaard, EPA/OAQPS/ESD/CPD, January 27. EC/R Incorporated (1995). Technical Memorandum from Amanda Williams to David Svendsgaard, EPA/OAPQS/ESD/CPD, July 7. Environmental Consulting and Research (1995). Spreadsheet file "m-empts.wk4," 7/12/95. Environmental Consulting and Research (1995). Spreadsheet file "s-nmsort.wk4," 7/13/95. Friedrich,Wolfgang (1994). Polyurethane Foam Recovers from Recession, in 1994/95 U.S. Foamed Plastics Markets & Directory, Technomic Publishing Co., Inc. Gallasch, H.F., Jr. (1984). "Price Elasticities of Demand at Retail and Wholesale Levels: An Automotive Example." Business Economics, 19:1, pp. 61-62. Harrington, James P. (1994). Review of the Plastic Foam Industry 1990-1993, in 1994/95 U.S. Foamed Plastics Markets & Directory, Technomic Publishing Co., Inc. Harrington, Ron and Kathy Hack (1991). Flexible Polyurethane Foams. Hull & Company (1992). End-Use Market Survey on the Polyurethane Industry in the U.S. and Canada, The Society of the Plastics Industry, Inc., Polyurethane Division, New York, New York. SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-38 ------- Mathtech (1994). Economic Impact and Regulatory Flexibility Analyses of the Wood Furniture NESHAP, Revised Draft Report. Prepared for the Cost and Economic Impact Section, Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. June. Nerlove, M. (1957). "A Note on the Long-Run Automobile Demand." Journal of Marketing, 22:1, pp. 57-64. Peters, Lou (1995). Telecomm. between Lou Peters and Jeffrey Sassin, 8/8/95. Robert Morris Associates. Annual Statement Studies, 1992 and 1993. Schultz, Steven A. (1989). Recent Developments in Flexible Polyurethane Foams (1980-1989), Masters Thesis, University of Lowell. Suite, D. (1958). "The Demand for New Automobiles in the United States, 1926-1956." Review of Economics and Statistics, 40:3, pp. 273-280. The Society of the Plastics Industry, Inc., Financial and Operating Ratios, Survey No. 30, Plastic Processing Companies, July 1992. U.S. Department of Commerce (1994). Census of Manufactures, 1992, Economics and Statistics Administration. SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-39 ------- SECTION 2 MODEL PLANTS AND COMPLIANCE TECHNOLOGIES Because plants in the flexible polyurethane industry are numerous, the analyses in this EIA rely on model plants. These model plants are characterized by product type (either molded or slabstock foam), production technology and production volume. MOLDED FOAM EPA estimates that there are approximately 234 molded foam production facilities in the United States. Each of these facilities is represented as one of four molded foam production model plants. One of these model plants (HP1) represents larger molded foam facilities using high-pressure mixheads, primarily to produce automobile seats. The remaining three model plants (LP1, LP2 and LP3) represent smaller producers that use low-pressure mixheads to produce a variety of foam products. Table 2-1 describes the baseline parameters of the molded foam model plants. For example, model plant HP1 produces up to 15,000 tons of molded foam annually (average annual production volume is 3,331 tons), represents 27 facilities nationwide, and has average annual emissions of 2.09 tons. SECTION 1: INDUSTRY PROFILE 1-40 ------- Molded Foam: Emission Controls Only major sources of HAP will be subject to the foam production NESHAP. Since the high-pressure molded foam plants and the smallest low-pressure molded foam plants have emissions below the major source threshold, we assume that the facilities represented by these model plants (HP1 and LP1) will not be affected by the NESHAP. Therefore, the estimated impacts presented in this report for molded foam are based on compliance costs and emission reductions associated with the production facilities represented by model plants LP2 and LP3. SECTION 2 - MODEL PLANTS AND COMPLIANCE TECHNOLOGIES 2-41 ------- Table 2-1 MOLDED FOAM MODEL PLANT BASELINE PARAMETERS Foam production range (tons/yr) Average foam production (tons/yr) Number of facilities represented Model plant emissions (tons/yr) HP1 0-15,000 3,331 27 2.09 LP1 0-99 26 109 5.29 LP2 100-499 308 54 19.81 LP3 >499 2,718 44 28.66 Source: EC/R Incorporated (1996a). Model plant compliance costs and emission reductions were estimated for a number of technologies to bring the following molded foam production source types into compliance: • Mixhead flushing. • Mold release agents. • Repair adhesive. Mixhead flushing emissions require no control under the MACT Floor, while Alternatives 1 and 2 prohibit the use of HAP flushes. Model plant compliance costs were estimated for four compliance technologies for mixhead flushing emissions: work practices for Regulatory Alternative 1; and non-HAP flushes, high pressure mixheads, and self-cleaning mixheads for Regulatory Alternative 2. All three regulatory alternatives prohibit the use of HAP-based mold release agents, resulting in 100 percent emission reduction for this source type. Model plant SECTION 2 - MODEL PLANTS AND COMPLIANCE TECHNOLOGIES 2-42 ------- compliance costs were estimated for three technologies that can achieve this result: reduced volatile organic compound (VOC) mold release agents, naphtha-based mold release agents, and water-based mold release agents. All three regulatory alternatives also prohibit the use HAP-based adhesives. Model plant costs were estimated for three technologies that can achieve this result: hot-melt adhesives, water-based adhesives, and hydrofuse adhesives. Molded Foam: Nationwide Compliance Costs and Emission Reductions Since different technologies (with different costs) can bring a source type into compliance, nationwide compliance costs depend on the compliance technologies chosen by affected plants. Table 2-2 gives the distribution of technologies assigned to model plants producing molded foam. Table 2-2 DISTRIBUTION OF COMPLIANCE TECHNOLOGIES FOR MOLDED FOAM MODEL PLANTS Emission Source/Technology Mixhead Flush Reg Alt 1 Solvent recovery Reg Alt II Non-HAP flush HP mixheads Mold Release Agents All Regulatory Alternatives Reduced VOC agents Naphtha-based agents Water- based agents Repair Adhesives All Regulatory Alternatives Hot-melt adhesives Water- based adhesives Number of Facilities with the Assigned Technology LP2 54 54 0 18 18 18 N/A N/A LP3 44 35 9 15 14 15 22 22 SECTION 2 - MODEL PLANTS AND COMPLIANCE TECHNOLOGIES 2-2 ------- Sources: EC/R Incorporated (1996a and 1996b). While Table 2-2 shows the assumed distributions of control technologies assigned to model plants for each emission source separately, it does not give the distribution for combinations of control technologies. For example, under Alternative 2, 35 of 44 LP3 type model plants are assumed to adopt non-HAP flush to control mixhead flush and 15 to adopt reduced VOC agents to control mold release agents. However, Table 2-2 does not show how many LP3 plants adopt non-HAP flush and reduced VOC agents. For the economic impact analysis, we assume that model plants adopt combinations of control technologies consistent with the proportions shown in Table 2-2. For example, we assume that 34 percent (15 of 44) of the 35 plants using non-HAP flush also use reduced VOC agents. We note, however, that the estimated impacts presented in this report are not sensitive to assumptions about the distribution of combinations of control technologies as long as some plants adopt the most costly combinations. The economic impacts are driven by the level of control costs facing the highest cost producers, and not necessarily the number of high cost producers. We report estimates of the nationwide compliance costs and emission reductions for molded foam plants in Table 2-3.18 For example, the MACT Floor would require affected molded foam plants to incur total, nationwide capital costs of $149,688, annual costs of $182,090, and would result in reduced HAP emissions of 331 tons annually. Annual costs include annual operating and maintenance (O&M) costs and amortized capital costs.19 Note that annual costs for the mixhead flush source type are negative under Alternative 1. This compliance technology is expected to result in net cost savings due to the salvaging and reuse of the mixhead flushing agent. In addition to the compliance costs reported in Table 2-3, the estimated economic impacts presented in this report include the effects of monitoring, inspection, 18 Appendix A provides detailed estimates of compliance costs and emission reductions by individual model plants, source types and control technologies. 19 Capital costs are amortized at 10 percent, assuming a 10-year equipment life. SECTION 2 - MODEL PLANTS AND COMPLIANCE TECHNOLOGIES 2-3 ------- recordkeeping and reporting (MIRR) costs at affected plants. Total annual MIRR costs are estimated as 10 Table 2-3 MOLDED FOAM NATIONWIDE COMPLIANCE COSTS Regulatory Alternative MACT Floor Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Regulatory Alternative 1 Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Regulatory Alternative 2 Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Impacts by Emission Source Mixhead Flush 0 0 0 4,630,500 (115,038) 1,501 5,923,125 524,098 2,001 Mold Release Agent 0 143,106 270 0 143,108 270 0 143,108 270 Repair Adhesive 149,688 38,984 61 149,688 38,984 61 149,688 38,984 61 Total 149,688 182,090 331 4,780,188 67,052 1,832 6,072,813 706,188 2,332 Sources: EC/R Incorporated (1996b and 1996c). percent of nationwide annual emission control costs.20 Annual MIRR costs per plant are estimated as nationwide MIRR costs for the industry segment divided by the number of affected plants in the industry segment. SLABSTOCK FOAM There are 78 slabstock facilities in the United States. Since slabstock foam is produced as large "buns" which must be cut into the desired sizes and shapes, fabrication operations are sometimes co-located with slabstock foam production 20 EC/R Incorporated (1996e). SECTION 2 - MODEL PLANTS AND COMPLIANCE TECHNOLOGIES 2-4 ------- facilities. As with molded foam, model plants were constructed to characterize the production volumes and production processes of the slabstock facilities. There are five basic model plants for slabstock foam (MP1, MP2, MP3, MP4 and MP5), each representing a range of production volume. Also, each basic model plant is separated into facilities that use MeCb as an equipment cleaner, and those that do not (e.g., MP1a uses MeCb as an equipment cleaner and MP1b does not). Table 2-4 describes the baseline parameters of the slabstock foam model plants. For example, model plant MP1 averages 2,000 tons of foam production annually and represents 19 plants nationwide. Model plant MP1a averages 64.19 tons of HAP emissions a year, while MP1b emits 59.19 tons annually. Table 2-4 SLABSTOCK FOAM MODEL PLANT BASELINE PARAMETERS Foam production range (tons/yr) Average foam production (tons/yr) Number of facilities represented Model plant (a) emissions (tons/yr) Model plant (b) emissions (tons/yr) MP1 0-3.9 2,000 19 64.19 59.19 MP2 4.0-7. 9 6,000 28 174.16 169.16 MP3 8.0-11.9 10,000 14 339.42 334.42 MP4 12.0-15.9 13,750 11 343.93 338.93 MP5 >15.9 19,000 6 388.53 383.53 Source: EC/R Incorporated (1996a). Slabstock Foam: Emission Controls Model plant compliance costs and emission reductions were estimated for a number of technologies to bring the following slabstock foam production source types into compliance: SECTION 2 - MODEL PLANTS AND COMPLIANCE TECHNOLOGIES 2-5 ------- • Storage/unloading. • Equipment cleaning. • Equipment leaks. • HAP auxiliary blowing agent (ABA) emissions. The MACT Floor level of control for storage and unloading of both TDI and HAP ABA is an equipment standard that requires either a vapor balance system to return the displaced HAP vapors to the tank truck or rail car, or a carbon canister through which emissions must be routed prior to being emitted to the atmosphere. Regulatory Alternatives 1 and 2 do not contain more stringent requirements for storage and unloading. The estimated costs and economic impacts presented in this report are based on the assumption that all affected plants adopt the vapor balance system. The MACT Floor level of control for equipment cleaning is the complete elimination of HAP emissions. Again, Regulatory Alternatives 1 and 2 do not contain more stringent requirements. The MACT Floor level of control for equipment leaks requires the use of sealless pumps for TDI transfer pumps. Regulatory Alternative 1 adds a unique LDAR program for HAP ABA components. Since Regulatory Alternative 2 does not allow the emission of any HAP ABA (which, in effect, prohibits the use of MeCI2 or any other HAP as an ABA), this alternative only contains the MACT Floor requirement for TDI pumps. There are three levels of control for HAP ABA emissions, one for each regulatory alternative. The MACT Floor and Regulatory Alternative 1 have emission limits based on product formulations. Applying the two sets of formulation limitations to the product mix of the model plants results in the emission reductions shown in Table 2-5. Regulatory Alternative 2 requires the complete elimination of HAP ABA emissions. SECTION 2 - MODEL PLANTS AND COMPLIANCE TECHNOLOGIES 2-6 ------- Table 2-5 SLABSTOCK MODEL PLANT HAP ABA EMISSION REDUCTIONS Model Plant Baseline HAP ABA Emissions (tons/yr) 1 2 3 4 5 55.0 165.0 330.0 335.0 380.0 HAP ABA Emission Reduction (tons/yr) MACT Floor 31.3 93.8 184.0 195.9 220.4 Reg Alt 1 35.9 111.7 220.7 235.7 266.0 Reg Alt 2 55.0 165.0 330.0 335.0 380.0 Sources: EC/R Incorporated (1996a and 1996b). There are several technologies available to reduce HAP ABA emissions to levels required by the regulatory alternatives. Table 2-6 lists these technologies for each regulatory alternative. Table 2-6 TECHNOLOGIES CAPABLE OF ACHIEVING HAP ABA REGULATORY ALTERNATIVE EMISSION LEVELS Regulatory Alternative MACT Floor Level Regulatory Alternative 1 Regulatory Alternative 2 Technology Chemical alternatives Carbon dioxide as an ABA (CarDio) Acetone as an ABA Variable pressure foaming (VPF) Forced cooling Carbon dioxide as an ABA Acetone as an ABA Variable pressure foaming Forced cooling Carbon dioxide plus chemical alternatives Acetone as an ABA Variable pressure foaming Forced cooling plus chemical SECTION 2 - MODEL PLANTS AND COMPLIANCE TECHNOLOGIES 2-7 ------- alternatives Source: EC/R Incorporated (1996a). As can be seen in Table 2-6, some technologies can be used to meet more than one level of control. In these cases, it was assumed that the technologies would only be used to the degree necessary to meet the level of the regulatory alternative. In other words, although variable pressure foaming can be used to totally eliminate the use of HAP ABA, it was assumed that for the MACT Floor, the allowable amount of MeCb would still be used and emitted. Table 2-7 gives the assumed distribution of HAP ABA emission control for technologies for the slabstock model plants. Since different technologies (with different costs) can bring a source type into compliance, nationwide compliance costs depend on the compliance technologies assigned to the model plants. Appendix D contains a sensitivity analysis of economic impacts when these compliance technology assignments are modified. Table 2-7 DISTRIBUTION OF HAP EMISSION REDUCTION TECHNOLOGIES Technology MACT Floor CarDio Acetone VPF Forced Cooling Chem Alternatives Reg Alt I CarDio Acetone VPF Forced Cooling Reg Alt II CarDio + Chem Alternatives Number of Facilities Using the Technology MP1 4 1 0 2 12 13 3 0 3 10 3 MP2 9 1 0 4 14 18 4 0 6 15 3 MP3 4 1 0 3 6 6 3 0 5 5 2 MP4 4 1 0 3 3 5 2 0 4 3 2 MP5 1 0 2 2 1 1 1 2 2 1 1 SECTION 2 - MODEL PLANTS AND COMPLIANCE TECHNOLOGIES 2-8 ------- Acetone VPF Forced Cooling + Chem Alts 0 6 1 9 1 6 2 4 2 2 Sources: EC/R Incorporated (1996a and 1996b). Slabstock Foam: Nationwide Compliance Costs and Emission Reductions Table 2-8 reports estimates of nationwide compliance costs and emission reductions for the slabstock foam industry segment.21 For example, the MACT Floor would require affected slabstock foam plants to incur nationwide capital costs of about $47 million and annual costs of about $11 million. Annual costs include O&M costs and amortized capital costs. The MACT Floor would reduce annual HAP emissions at slabstock foam plants by an estimated 9,422 tons annually. Costs are negative for equipment cleaning because this compliance technology is expected to result in net cost savings primarily due to reduced wast disposal costs by switching to non-HAP cleaning material. In addition to the compliance costs reported in Table 2-8, the estimated economic impacts presented in this report include the effects of monitoring, inspection, recordkeeping and reporting (MIRR) costs at affected slabstock plants. Total annual MIRR costs are estimated as 10 percent of nationwide annual emission control costs. Annual MIRR costs per plant are estimated as nationwide MIRR costs for the industry segment divided by the number of affected plants in the industry segment. 21 Appendix A provides detailed estimates of compliance costs and emission reductions by individual model plants, source types and control technologies. SECTION 2 - MODEL PLANTS AND COMPLIANCE TECHNOLOGIES 2-9 ------- Table 2-8 SLABSTOCK FOAM NATIONWIDE COMPLIANCE COSTS AND EMISSION REDUCTIONS Regulatory Alternative MACT Floor Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Regulatory Alternative 1 Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Regulatory Alternative 2 Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Impacts by Emission Source Storage/ Unloading 558,960 105,119 15 558,960 105,119 15 308,250 65,447 0 Equipment Leaks 95,000 24,035 3 682,754 489,455 80 95,000 24,035 3 Equipmen t Cleaning 0 (7,150) 130 0 (7,150) 130 0 (7,150) 130 ABA 46,362,700 10,925,497 9,274 66,981,900 6,241,347 1 1 ,262 93,665,425 10,346,338 16,250 Total 47,016,660 11,047,501 9,422 68,858,534 7,111,821 1 1 ,644 94,068,675 10,428,670 16,383 Sources: EC/R Incorporated (1996b, 1996cand 1996d). SECTION 2 - MODEL PLANTS AND COMPLIANCE TECHNOLOGIES 2-10 ------- REFERENCES EC/R Incorporated (1996a). Technical memorandum from Phil Norwood and Amanda Williams to David Svendsgaard (EPA/OAQPS), January 26. EC/R Incorporated (1996b). Technical memorandum from Phil Norwood to Jeffrey Sassin (Mathtech), February 18. EC/R Incorporated (1996c). Technical memorandum from Phil Norwood to David Svendsgaard and Lisa Conner (EPA/OAQPS), March 26. EC/R Incorporated (1996d). Technical memorandum from Phil Norwood to Jeffrey Sassin (Mathtech), June 6. EC/R Incorporated (1996e). Technical memorandum from Phil Norwood to Jeffrey Sassin (Mathtech), March 25. SECTION 3 SECTION 2 - MODEL PLANTS AND COMPLIANCE TECHNOLOGIES 2-11 ------- ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS METHODOLOGY We assess the economic impacts associated with the alternative NESHAPs by conducting studies of the affected industry segments. These industry segments are flexible polyurethane slabstock foam and flexible polyurethane molded foam. We describe the analytical methods employed in these studies below. OVERVIEW OF DISTRIBUTIONAL IMPACTS As noted earlier in the introduction to this report, several groups might potentially suffer from adverse impacts associated with the alternative NESHAPs. These groups include: • Foam producers. • Foam buyers. • Employees at affected plants. • Individuals affected indirectly by the NESHAP. We describe the potential adverse impacts affecting each of these groups below. Impacts on Producers As affected producers purchase, install and operate emission control equipment or change production practices to comply with the standard, their costs will increase, reducing the profitability of at least some of the affected plants. However, a portion of the compliance costs can be passed on to consumers through increased product prices. Ultimately, the magnitude of the adverse impacts incurred by affected plants will depend on the extent to which control costs can be passed on to buyers. SECTIONS: ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS METHODOLOGY 3-2 ------- Some plants in the affected industry may not suffer adverse impacts as a result of the implementation of an emission control standard. The post-control profitability of an affected plant will improve if post-control price increases more than offset the plant's emission control costs. This could occur if control costs for some plants are substantially higher, per unit of output, than those for other plants in the industry. Also, plants not affected by the standard may enjoy the benefit of higher market prices without incurring the additional operating costs associated with compliance. An impact on producers that cannot be measured in this analysis is the affect of a potential change in product quality. Industry representatives maintain that the effect of a few of the control technologies on product quality is uncertain. If the use of these technologies causes quality degradation, foam producers might face reduced demand for their output. Impacts on Consumers or Buyers Both slabstock and molded foam are purchased primarily by firms which use these products as inputs to produce other goods. These firms and the consumers of the goods which they produce are likely to suffer from two related adverse impacts. First, post- control prices for foam produced at the affected plants are likely to be higher as sellers attempt to pass through some of the costs of emission controls. This will cause profits to be smaller, at least in the short run, for firms which purchase slabstock and molded foam as inputs to other final goods such as automobiles. It will also cause prices of final goods to be higher as firms attempt to pass through some of the increase in production costs. Second, the shift in supply caused by emission control costs is likely to reduce the amount of foam sold in affected markets, as well as the level of output sold in markets which use the foam as an input. These two effects are related in that post-control equilibrium prices and output levels in affected markets will be determined simultaneously. Also, customers of foam producers might suffer adverse impacts if the use of a control technology causes quality degradation. SECTIONS: ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS METHODOLOGY 3-3 ------- Indirect or Secondary Impacts Two countervailing impacts on employees of affected plants are likely to result from the implementation of the alternative NESHAPs. Employment will fall if affected plants either reduce output or close operations altogether. If this occurs, firms that supply inputs to foam producers might also suffer adverse impacts. On the other hand, increases in employment associated with the installation, operation, maintenance and monitoring of emission controls are likely. Also, firms that produce substitutes to foam products could benefit from reduced foam production. A number of other indirect or secondary adverse impacts may be associated with the implementation of a standard. The indirect impacts we consider in this study in- clude: impacts on regional economies and effects on energy consumption. We also assess potential small business impacts. ECONOMIC IMPACT STUDIES The industry segment studies that follow in this report include six major components of analysis. These components or phases of analysis, which are designed to measure and describe economic impacts, are: • Industry profile. • Direct impacts (market price and output, domestic production and plant closures). • Capital availability analysis. • Evaluation of secondary impacts (employment, foreign trade, energy consumption, and regional and local impacts). • Analysis of potential small business impacts. SECTIONS: ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS METHODOLOGY 3-4 ------- Each of these phases of analysis is described below. INDUSTRY PROFILE The industry profile provided in Section 3 describes conditions in affected industry segments that are likely to determine the nature of economic impacts associated with the implementation of the NESHAP. We discuss the following seven topics in the industry profile: • Product descriptions. • Prices and output. • Market outlook. • Market structure. • Foreign trade. • Financial conditions. • Employment and energy use. PRIMARY IMPACTS We employ a partial equilibrium model of the slabstock and molded foam segments to estimate the primary impacts of emission control costs, including market equilibrium prices, market output levels, the value of domestic shipments, and the number of potential plant closures.22 This analysis is so named because the predicted impacts are driven by estimates of how the affected industries achieve market equilibrium after the regulatory alternatives are implemented. 22 The results of the partial equilibrium analyses are also used to estimate employment, energy and foreign trade impacts and the economic costs associated with the regulatory alternatives. SECTIONS: ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS METHODOLOGY 3-5 ------- In a competitive market, equilibrium price and output are determined by the inter- section of demand and supply. The supply function is determined by the marginal (avoidable) operating costs of existing plants and potential entrants. A plant will be willing to supply output so long as market price exceeds its average (avoidable) operating costs. The installation, operation, maintenance and monitoring of emission controls will result in an increase in operating costs. An associated upward shift in the supply function will occur. The procedures employed in the market analysis are illus- trated in Figure 3-1. Constructing the model and predicting impacts requires completing the following four tasks. Pre-Control Market Data Specify Demand and Supply Functions Emissions Control Costs Discounted Cash Flow Parameters 1 Estimate Pre-Control Demand and Supply Estimate per Unit Emissions Control Costs Construct Post-Control Supply Function Solve for Post Control Price and Output, and Predict Closures SECTION 3: ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS METHODOLOGY 3-6 ------- Figure 3-1 Partial Equilibrium Analysis of Slabstock and Molded Foam Industry Segments • Estimate pre-control market demand and supply functions. • Estimate per unit emission control costs. • Construct the post-control supply function. • Solve for post-control price, output and employment levels, and predict plant closures. We briefly describe each of these tasks below.23 Pre-Control Market Demand and Supply Functions Pre-control equilibrium price and output levels in competitive markets are determined by market demand and supply. When the supply curve shifts because of compliance costs, the economic impacts are driven primarily by market demand and supply elasticities. Unfortunately, estimates of demand and supply elasticities for the affected industry segments are not available in the economic literature and the data required to obtain estimates tailored for this study are unavailable. We expect that the market demand for flexible foam is relatively inelastic (i.e., changes in price will have only a small affect on the level of output), because (1) close substitutes for the product are unavailable, and (2) the foam content of final products generally comprises only a small fraction of total product cost. The base case results reported in the text of this report are based on an assumed demand elasticity of -0.5. In Appendix C, we report the results of sensitivity analyses for which we assume a high demand elasticity of -1.0 and a low demand elasticity of -0.25. 23 See Appendices A, and B for more detailed descriptions of the data and methods employed in the partial equilibrium analysis. SECTIONS: ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS METHODOLOGY 3-7 ------- Unfortunately, we have little a priori basis for restricting the range for the market supply elasticity. The base case results reported in the text of this report are based on relatively elastic supply of 10.0. In Appendix C, we report the results of sensitivity analyses for which we assume a high supply elasticity of 50.0 and a low supply elasticity of 5.0. Per Unit Emission Control Costs Emission control costs will cause an upward vertical shift of the supply curves in affected markets. The height of the vertical shift for each affected plant is given by the after-tax cash flow required to offset the per unit increase in production costs resulting from the installation, maintenance, operation and monitoring of emission control equipment. Estimates of the capital, operating, maintenance and monitoring costs associated with emission controls for affected plants are reported in Appendix A. Per unit, after-tax costs are estimated by dividing after-tax annualized costs by annual output.24 This cost reflects the offsetting cash flow requirement which, in turn, yields an estimate of the post-control vertical shift in the supply function. Computing per unit after-tax control costs requires, as inputs, estimates of the following parameters: • The useful life of emission control equipment. • The discount rate (marginal cost of capital). • The marginal corporate income tax rate. 24 Our use of after-tax costs is consistent with the assumption that firms attempt to maximize after-tax profits. An alternative view is that what matters to the firm are costs net of any adjustments for taxes. Thus, the use of after-tax costs is consistent both with rational behavior by affected firms and our objective of predicting how the market will respond to implementation of the regulatory alternatives. SECTIONS: ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS METHODOLOGY 3-8 ------- The expected life of emission control equipment for slabstock and molded foam plants is 10 years. The economic impacts presented in this report are based on a 10 percent real private discount rate25 and a 25 percent marginal tax rate. The Post-Control Supply Function Estimated after-tax per unit control costs are added to pre-control supply prices to determine the post-control supply prices for affected producers. We construct the post-control domestic supply function by sorting affected plants, from highest to lowest, by per unit post-control costs. We assume that plants with the highest per unit emission control costs are marginal (i.e., have the highest cost) in the post-control market. We define the "marginal" plant as the plant with the highest per unit operating costs in the market. As price adjusts to competition among producers, unprofitable producers exit the market until price rests at equilibrium. At equilibrium, the market price must be high enough to cover the per unit avoidable costs of the marginal plant, the highest-cost plant remaining in the market. Post-Control Prices. Output, and Closures The baseline, pre-control equilibrium output in an affected market is taken as the level of observed national consumption. We compute post-control equilibrium price and output levels in affected markets by solving for the intersection of the market demand curve and the market post-control, segmented supply curve. The estimated reduction in market output is given by the difference between the observed pre-control output level and the predicted post-control output level. Similarly, the estimated in- 25 The discount rate referred to here measures the private marginal cost of capital to affected firms. This rate, which is used to predict the market responses of affected firms to emission control costs, should be distinguished from the social cost of capital. The social cost of capital is used to measure the economic costs of emission controls. See Section 7 for a more detailed discussion of this issue. SECTIONS: ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS METHODOLOGY 3-9 ------- crease in price is taken as the difference between the observed pre-control price and the predicted post-control equilibrium price. Reporting Results of Market Analyses The results of the partial equilibrium market analyses for each of the affected industries are presented in Section 4 of this report. In particular, estimates of the following are reported: • Price increase. • Reduction in market output. • Annual change in the value of domestic shipments. • Number of plant closures. Limitations of the Market Analysis The partial equilibrium model has a number of limitations. First, a single national market for homogeneous output is assumed in the analysis. However, as explained in Section 2, due to the nature of the product, markets may be regional. Because of transportation costs, foam producers tend to be located proximate to end-use markets. Each regional market will be affected primarily by cost changes of plants in the region, rather than all plants in the national market. Output reductions and price effects will vary across regions depending on locations of affected plants. The assumption of a national market is likely to cause predicted closures to be overstated to the extent that affected firms are protected somewhat by regional trade barriers. Second, the analysis assumes that plants with the highest per unit compliance costs are marginal post-control. This assumption produces an upward bias in estimated effects on industry output and price changes because the control costs of non-marginal plants will not affect market price. This also results in predicted closures SECTIONS: ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS METHODOLOGY 3-10 ------- to be overstated. Plants with the highest per unit emission control costs might not be marginal if other plants with lower per unit emission control costs experience higher baseline costs. These other plants would be marginal if higher baseline costs more than offset the lower compliance costs. Third, the analysis assumes that the implementation of controls does not induce any domestic producers to expand production. An incentive for expansion would exist if some plants have post-control incremental unit costs between the baseline price and the post-control price predicted by the partial equilibrium analysis. Plants unaffected by the standard may indeed face this incentive to expand production. Expansion by domestic producers will result in reduced impacts on industry output and price levels. While plant closures will increase as expanding producers squeeze out plants with higher post-control costs, net closures (closures minus expansions) will be reduced. Fourth, the effect of using chemical alternatives on product quality is uncertain. If using chemical alternatives as a control strategy causes quality degradation, the estimates of impacts presented in this report could be understated. Finally, estimates of demand and supply elasticities are unavailable and the base case results presented in the text of this report are based on assumed values to characterize the relative importance of elasticity. In the analyses reported in Appendix C, we assess the sensitivity of the estimated impacts to ranges of assumed values for the elasticities. In addition, it is likely that uncertainty in the estimates of compliance costs exist, causing costs for some plants to be either overstated or understated. The estimated impacts also depend on assumptions about which control strategies plants adopt. We report estimates of impacts based on alternative assumption about control strategy selections in Appendix D. CAPITAL AVAILABILITY ANALYSIS SECTION 3: ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS METHODOLOGY 3-11 ------- We assume in the market analysis that affected firms will be able to raise the capital associated with controlling emissions at a specified marginal cost of capital. The capital availability analysis, on the other hand, examines the variation in firms' ability to raise the capital necessary for the purchase, installation, and testing of emission control equipment. The capital availability analysis also serves three other purposes. First, it provides information for evaluating the appropriateness of the selected discount rate as a proxy for the marginal cost of capital of the industry; implications for bias in the partial equilibrium analysis follow. Second, it provides information on potential variation in capital costs across firms. Third, it provides measures of the potential impacts of controls on the profitability of affected firms. Evaluation of Impacts on Capital Availability For each model plant26 included in the capital availability analysis, the impact of the regulatory alternatives on the following two measures is evaluated: • Net income/assets. • Long-term debt/long-term debt and equity. Net income is measured before-tax and is defined to include all operations, continued and discontinued. The ratio of net income to assets is a measure of return on investment. The implementation of emission controls is likely to reduce this ratio to the extent that net income falls (e.g., because of higher operating costs) and assets increase (because of investments in emission control equipment). 26 The model plants included in the analysis are described in more detail in Appendix A. SECTIONS: ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS METHODOLOGY 3-12 ------- The ratio of long-term debt to long-term debt plus equity is a measure of risk perceived by potential investors. Other things being the same, a firm with a high debt-equity ratio is likely to be perceived as being more risky, and as a result, may encounter difficulty in raising capital. This ratio will increase if affected firms purchase emission control equipment by issuing long-term debt. Baseline Values for Capital Availability Analysis -- Baseline values for net income and net income/assets are derived by averaging data that are available between 1991 and 1993. Data from several years are employed to reduce distortions caused by year-to-year fluctuations. Since changes in the long-term debt ratio represent actual structural changes, data for the most recent year available are used. Post-Control Values for Capital Availability Analysis -- Post-control values for the two measures identified above are computed to evaluate the ability of affected firms to raise required capital. The post control values are computed as follows: • Post-control net income — pre-control before-tax net income plus additional revenues due to higher post-control prices minus the annualized compliance costs. • Post-control return on assets — post-control net income divided by the sum of pre-control assets plus investments in emission control equipment. • Post-control long-term debt ratio — the sum of pre-control long-term debt and investments in emission control equipment divided by the sum of pre-control long-term debt, equity, and investments in emission control equipment. Note that post-control return on assets is adjusted for higher post-control prices predicted in the partial equilibrium analysis. However, we adopt a worst-case SECTIONS: ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS METHODOLOGY 3-13 ------- assumption for the debt ratio in that we assume that the total investment in emission control equipment is debt-financed rather than paid for out of cash flow. Limitations of the Capital-Availability Analysis - The first limitation of the capital availability analysis is that future baseline perfor- mance may deviate from past levels. The financial position of a firm during the period 1991-1993 may not be a good approximation of the company's position later during the implementation period, even in the absence of the impacts of emission control costs. Second, a limited set of measures is used to evaluate the impact of controls. These measures reflect accounting conventions and provide only a rough approximation of the factors that will influence capital availability. Third, financial data are not available for all firms expected to be affected by the regulatory alternatives. Financial data tend to be available for larger, publicly-held firms. These companies might not be representative of all affected firms. EVALUATION OF SECONDARY IMPACTS The secondary impacts that we consider in this study include: • Employment impacts. • Energy impacts. • Foreign trade impacts. • Regional impacts. Employment Impacts SECTIONS: ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS METHODOLOGY 3-14 ------- As equilibrium output in affected industry segments falls because of control costs, employment in the industry will decrease. On the other hand, operating and maintaining emission control equipment requires additional labor for some control options. Direct net employment impacts are equal to the decrease in employment due to output reductions, less the increase in employment associated with the operation and maintenance of emission control equipment. The estimates of the employment impacts associated with the alternative NESHAPs are based on employment-output ratios and estimated changes in domestic production. Specifically, we compute changes in employment proportional to estimated changes in domestic production.27 Estimates of the labor hours required to operate and maintain emission control equipment are unavailable. Accordingly, the employment impacts presented in this report are overstated to the extent that potential employment gains attributable to oper- ating and maintaining control equipment are not considered. Also, we do not include estimates of employment impacts at firms indirectly affected by the regulatory alternatives, such as those at firms selling inputs to the flexible foam industry. The estimates of direct employment impacts are driven by estimates of output reductions obtained in the market analyses. Biases in these estimates will likely cause the estimates of employment impacts to be biased in the same direction. Energy Effects The energy effects associated with the alternative NESHAPs include reduced energy consumption due to reduced output in affected industry segments plus the net change in energy consumption associated with the operation of emission controls. 27 See Appendix B for descriptions of the data and methods used to estimate employment impacts. SECTIONS: ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS METHODOLOGY 3-15 ------- The method we use to estimate reduced energy consumption due to output reductions is similar to the approach employed for estimating employment impacts.28 Specifically, we assume that changes in energy use are proportional to estimated changes in domestic production. Estimates of the net change in energy consumption due to operating emission controls are unavailable.29 Regional Impacts Substantial regional or community impacts may occur if a plant that employs a significant percent of the local population or contributes importantly to the local tax base is forced to close or to reduce output because of emission control costs. Secondary employment impacts may be generated if a substantial number of plants close as a result of emission control costs. Secondary employment impacts include those suffered by employees of firms that provide inputs to the directly affected industry, employees of firms that purchase inputs from directly affected firms for end-use products, and employees of other local businesses. 28 See Appendix B for a more detailed description of this procedure. 29 We view these as short-run estimates of reduced energy consumption. In the long run, resources diverted from the production of flexible foam will likely be directed to producing other goods and services. SECTIONS: ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS METHODOLOGY 3-16 ------- SECTION 4 PRIMARY ECONOMIC IMPACTS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY ANALYSIS INTRODUCTION This section presents estimates of the primary economic impacts of the alternative NESHAPs on the slabstock and molded foam segments of the flexible polyurethane foam industry. Primary impacts include changes in market prices and output levels, changes in the value of shipments by domestic producers, and plant closures. For the slabstock industry sector, we report a range of plant closures based on the results of a sensitivity analysis reported in Appendix D. We also present the results of the capital availability analysis for the two industry segments. The capital availability analysis assesses the ability of affected firms to raise capital and assesses the impacts of control costs on plant profitability. We consider the three regulatory alternatives, the MACT floor, Regulatory Alternative 1, and Regulatory Alternative 2 in our analyses. ESTIMATES OF PRIMARY IMPACTS As explained earlier in Section 3, we use partial equilibrium models of the affected industry segments to estimate primary impacts. The increase in production costs resulting from the purchase and operation of emission control equipment causes upward, vertical shifts in the industry supply curves. The height of these shifts is deter- mined by the after tax cash flow required to offset the per unit increase in production SECTION 3: ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS METHODOLOGY 3-17 ------- costs resulting from compliance. Because control costs vary across plants within each industry segment, the post-control supply curves are segmented. We assume a worst case scenario in which plants with the highest control costs (per unit of output) are marginal (highest cost) in the post-control market. We assume that the alternative NESHAPs will not affect foreign trade in foam products. Given the nature of the product, foreign trade in flexible polyurethane foam is negligible. It is a large volume product with very little cost (value) per unit weight. Shipping a cargo of foam is similar to shipping "air." High transportation costs relative to foam value makes long distance foam transport uneconomical. However, some international trade in flexible polyurethane foam exists in the form of end-use products (e.g., in automobiles). Table 4-1 presents the primary impacts predicted by the partial equilibrium analysis for the flexible slabstock and flexible molded foam segments. For example, we estimate that the implementation of the MACT floor will result in a $0.03/lb (2.28 per- cent) increase in the price of slabstock foam and an annual reduction in domestic production of 6.87 thousand tons (1.12 percent of baseline production). Although the industry faces compliance costs resulting from the rule, the analysis shows that the MACT floor will cause the annual value of domestic shipments to increase by $19.53 million (1.14 percent). The value of shipments increases because the price increase more than offsets the reduction in output. We estimate that the MACT Floor will result in one to two slabstock plant closures. The range of estimates of plant closures reflects alternative assumptions about which control strategies slabstock plants adopt.30 30 See Appendix D for a more detailed discussion of this issue. SECTION 4 - PRIMARY ECONOMIC IMPACTS AND CAPITAL A VAILABILITY ANALYSIS 4-2 ------- Table 4-1 ESTIMATED PRIMARY IMPACTS ON THE FLEXIBLE SLABSTOCK FOAM MARKET Impact Price Change $/lb percent Annual Change in Domestic Output 1 000 tons/yr percent Annual Change in Value of Shipments $milliona percent Plant Closures'3 MACT Floor .03 2.28 -6.87 -1.12 19.53 1.14 1 to 2 Reg. Alt I .03 2.20 -6.62 -1.08 18.82 1.10 1 to 3 Reg. Alt II .05 3.82 -11.36 -1.86 32.56 1.89 1 to 4 1994 dollars. Ranges of predicted plant closures reflect alternative assumptions about different control technologies adopted by model plants. Table 4-1 also shows the estimated primary impacts from the implementation of Regulatory Alternatives 1 and 2. Slabstock foam price increases are estimated to be $0.03/lb (2.20 percent) under Regulatory Alternative 1, and $0.05/lb (3.82 percent) under Regulatory Alternative 2. We estimate decreases in annual domestic output of 6.62 thousand tons (1.08 percent) under Alternative 1, and 11.36 thousand tons (1.86 percent) under Alternative 2. Our analysis predicts one to three plant closures for Regulatory Alternative 1 and one to four plant closures under Regulatory Alternative 2. As with the MACT floor, increases in the value of shipments are predicted under both regulatory alternatives. We estimate increases in the value of domestic shipments of $18.82 million (1.10 percent) under Regulatory Alternative 1 and $32.56 million (1.89 percent) under Regulatory Alternative 2. Table 4-2 displays estimated primary impacts on the molded foam industry. We estimate that the implementation of the MACT floor will result in a $0.0017/lb (0.07 SECTION 4 - PRIMARY ECONOMIC IMPACTS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY ANALYSIS 4-3 ------- percent) increase in the price of molded foam. The associated reduction in domestic production is estimated to be 0.09 thousand tons (0.04 percent), and no plant closures are predicted. The estimated effect of the MACT floor on the value of domestic shipments is small, about $390 thousand (0.04 percent). Table 4-2 ESTIMATED PRIMARY IMPACTS ON THE FLEXIBLE MOLDED FOAM MARKET Impact Price Change $/lb percent Annual Change in Domestic Output 1 000 tons/yr percent Annual Change in Value of Shipments $Milliona percent Plant Closures MACT Floor 0.00 0.07 -0.09 -0.04 0.39 0.04 0 Reg. Alt 1 0.02 0.84 -0.95 -0.42 4.50 0.42 3 Reg. Alt 2 0.03 1.14 -1.29 -0.56 6.10 0.57 0 1994 dollars. Table 4-2 also displays the estimated primary impacts of Regulatory Alternatives 1 and 2 on the molded foam segment. Foam price increases are estimated to be $0.02/lb (0.84 percent) under Regulatory Alternative 1, and $0.03/lb (1.14 percent) under Regulatory Alternative 2. We estimate decreases in annual domestic output of 0.95 thousand tons (0.42 percent) under Alternative 1, and 1.29 thousand tons (0.56 percent) under Alternative 2. Annual increases in the value of shipments are expected under both regulatory alternatives. We estimate increases in the value of domestic shipments of $4.50 million (0.42 percent) under Regulatory Alternative 1 and $6.10 million (0.57 SECTION 4 - PRIMARY ECONOMIC IMPACTS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY ANALYSIS 4-4 ------- percent) under Regulatory Alternative 2. Our analysis predicts three plant closures under Regulatory Alternative 1 and no plant closures under Regulatory Alternative 2. We emphasize that many of the assumptions we adopt in the analysis are likely to cause an overestimate of predicted plant closures. First, we assume that the plant with the highest per unit emission control costs also is the least efficient in that it has the highest baseline per unit production costs. Second, we assume a national market, but regional trade barriers might afford some protection for some plants. The costs of the available technologies for complying with the alternative NESHAPs vary substantially for slabstock plants. Some plants might adopt less costly technologies than those assigned in this analysis, thus reducing compliance costs and plant closures. By altering the assumptions about the technologies some model plants employ to achieve ABA emission reductions, the count of predicted plant closures changes. As Appendix D demonstrates, replacing the Forced Cooling technology with Acetone will reduce predicted slabstock closures from 2 to 1 under the MACT floor, from 3 to 1 under Regulatory Alternative 1, and from 4 to 1 under Regulatory Alternative 2. The estimated primary impacts reported above depend on a set of parameters used in the partial equilibrium model of the slabstock and molded foam industries. One of the parameters, the elasticity of demand, measures how sensitive buyers are to price changes. A second parameter, the elasticity of supply, measures how sensitive suppliers, or producers, are to price changes. For this analysis, we were not able to find supply or demand elasticity estimates for either industry segment in the literature. Also, we were unable to identify data required to derive our own estimates. The estimated impacts reported above in Tables 4-1 and 4-2 are based on a demand elasticity of -0.5 and a supply elasticity of 10.0 for both the slabstock and molded foam segments. In Appendix C, we report the results of analyses that show the sensitivity of the estimated impacts to changes in these elasticity estimates. The "low" elasticity case adopts a demand elasticity of -0.25 and a supply elasticity of 5.0 for both markets (slabstock and molded). These results show smaller reductions in market SECTION 4 - PRIMARY ECONOMIC IMPACTS AND CAPITAL A VAILABILITY ANALYSIS 4-5 ------- output and generally slightly less adverse impacts on domestic producers than results reported above. The "high" elasticity case reported in Appendix C employs a demand elasticity of -1.0 and a supply elasticity of 50.0 for both markets. In general, this case shows slightly more adverse impacts on domestic producers. However, the sensitivity analyses generally show that the estimated primary impacts are relatively insensitive to reasonable ranges of demand and supply elasticity estimates. CAPITAL AVAILABILITY ANALYSIS The capital availability analysis involves examining pre- and post-control values of selected financial ratios. These ratios include net income divided by assets and long term debt divided by the sum of long term debt and equity. In order to reduce the effects of year-to-year fluctuations in net income, a three-year average (1991 through 1993) of net income over assets was used as the baseline. Changes in the long term debt ratio represent structural changes and so are not subject to the same cyclical fluctuations. Long term debt ratios from 1993 were used as the baseline. As explained in Section 3, these financial statistics lend insight into the ability of affected firms to raise the capital needed to acquire emission controls. They also provide estimates of the changes in profitability which would arise from the implementation of the NESHAP. To calculate the post-control ratio of net income to assets, additional revenues due to higher post-control prices less annualized control costs were added to pre-control net income, and capital control costs were added to pre-control assets. To calculate the post-control long term debt ratio, capital control costs were added to pre-control long term debt, both in the numerator and denominator of this ratio. Note that we have adjusted the return on assets measure for higher post-control prices. However, the post-control debt ratios reflect a worst-case assumption that affected firms are required to finance emission controls entirely through debt. Second, for this analysis we assume that production facilities will choose the highest cost (capital cost) SECTION 4 - PRIMARY ECONOMIC IMPACTS AND CAPITAL A VAILABILITY ANALYSIS 4-6 ------- compliance technology. In reality, some facilities may choose other technologies with lower costs. As discussed in Section 1, the slabstock and molded foam industries are characterized by individual firms owning multiple production facilities. Financial data are available for only 7 of the 28 firms which produce slabstock. This represents 26 of the 78 production facilities nationwide. Data for the molded sector were only available for 9 firms. These 9 firms operate 17 of the approximately 234 production facilities nationwide. Tables 4-3 through 4-5 show the results of the capital availability analyses conducted for the three regulatory alternatives. Note that the company number identification corresponds with those found in Table 1-13. In many cases, the regulatory alternatives have a negligible effect on the ratio of net income to assets for affected companies (i.e., the impacts round to zero at two significant digits). The largest declines in this ratio are very small, in the neighborhood of about one-tenth of a percent. Note that the post-control net income to assets ratio increases relative to the baseline for some affected companies. This occurs when additional revenues from higher post-control prices more than offset compliance costs. Similarly, effects of the regulatory alternatives on the long-term debt ratios appears to be negligible in most cases. Except for Companies 24 and 25, the post-control debt ratios are all within one percent of pre-control levels. Even after controls, Companies 24 and 25 appear to have long-term debt ratios typical of the industry. All of the companies with available data are large publicly held corporations. As a result, emission controls costs, which are small relative to their overall financial resources, have no significant impacts on the firms' financial ratios. Accordingly, we conclude that the companies which we analyzed will not find it difficult to raise the capital necessary to purchase and install the required emission controls. We note, SECTION 4 - PRIMARY ECONOMIC IMPACTS AND CAPITAL A VAILABILITY ANALYSIS 4-7 ------- however, that the firms for which financial data are available might not be representative of other affected firms in the industry. SECTION 4 - PRIMARY ECONOMIC IMPACTS AND CAPITAL A VAILABILITY ANALYSIS 4-8 ------- Table 4-3 CAPITAL AVAILABILITY ANALYSIS MACT FLOOR FIRM Company 1 Company 3 Company 7 Company 8 Company 9 Company 10 Company 11 Company 19 Company 20 Company 24 Company 25 Company 27 Company 30 Company 35 PRE-CONTROL NI/Aa (Percent) 2.57 -1.37 2.23 -0.65 2.22 4.02 6.79 4.49 -1.17 12.93 7.78 5.52 1.43 -0.87 LTD/(LTD+E)b (Percent) 13.41 19.41 11.21 23.56 21.40 15.53 15.17 26.32 11.13 21.70 10.59 31.84 42.22 9.99 POST-CONTROL NI/Aa (Percent) 2.57 -1.37 2.22 -0.65 3.60 4.02 6.79 4.47 -1.17 12.95 7.80 5.46 1.45 -0.87 LTD/(LTD+E)b (Percent) 13.41 19.41 11.21 23.57 22.22 15.53 15.17 26.34 11.13 23.65 13.24 32.20 42.33 10.16 Notes: a Net income divided by assets (1991-1993 average). b Long-term debt divided by long-term debt plus equity (1993). Sources: Moody's Industrial Manual, 1994; Moody's OTC Industrial Manual, 1994' Moody's OTC Unlisted Manual, Dun & Bradstreet's Million Dollar Directory, 1994; Herman Miller Annual Reports, 1989-1991. SECTION 4 - PRIMARY ECONOMIC IMPACTS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY ANALYSIS 4-9 ------- Table 4-4 CAPITAL AVAILABILITY ANALYSIS REGULATORY ALTERNATIVE 1 FIRM Company 1 Company 3 Company 7 Company 8 Company 9 Company 10 Company 11 Company 19 Company 20 Company 24 Company 25 Company 27 Company 30 Company 35 PRE-CONTROL NI/Aa (Percent) 2.57 -1.37 2.23 -0.65 2.22 4.02 6.79 4.49 -1.17 12.93 7.78 5.52 1.43 -0.87 LTD/(LTD+E)b (Percent) 13.41 19.41 11.21 23.56 21.40 15.53 15.17 26.32 11.13 21.70 10.59 31.84 42.22 9.99 POST-CONTROL NI/Aa (Percent) 2.61 -1.37 2.27 -0.65 3.86 4.04 6.79 4.47 -1.17 12.95 7.81 5.47 1.44 -0.87 LTD/(LTD+E)b (Percent) 13.42 19.41 11.21 23.57 22.13 15.53 15.18 26.34 11.13 23.65 13.24 32.20 42.33 10.16 Notes: 3 Net income divided by assets (1991-1993 average). b Long-term debt divided by long-term debt plus equity (1993). Sources: Moody's Industrial Manual, 1994; Moody's OTC Industrial Manual, 1994' Moody's OTC Unlisted Manual, Dun & Bradstreet's Million Dollar Directory, 1994; Herman Miller Annual Reports, 1989-1991. SECTION 4 - PRIMARY ECONOMIC IMPACTS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY ANALYSIS 4-10 ------- Table 4-5 CAPITAL AVAILABILITY ANALYSIS REGULATORY ALTERNATIVE 2 FIRM Company 1 Company 3 Company 7 Company 8 Company 9 Company 10 Company 11 Company 19 Company 20 Company 24 Company 25 Company 27 Company 30 Company 35 PRE-CONTROL NI/Aa (Percent) 2.57 -1.37 2.23 -0.65 2.22 4.02 6.79 4.49 -1.17 12.93 7.78 5.52 1.43 -0.87 LTD/(LTD+E)b (Percent) 13.41 19.41 11.21 23.56 21.40 15.53 15.17 26.32 11.13 21.70 10.59 31.84 42.22 9.99 POST-CONTROL NI/Aa (Percent) 2.60 -1.37 2.10 -0.65 4.57 3.93 6.76 4.47 -1.17 13.05 7.74 5.54 1.44 -0.87 LTD/(LTD+E)b (Percent) 13.50 19.41 11.23 23.59 22.52 15.63 15.28 26.34 11.13 24.07 16.35 32.34 42.46 10.16 Notes: a Net income divided by assets (1991-1993 average). b Long-term debt divided by long-term debt plus equity (1993). Sources: Moody's Industrial Manual, 1994; Moody's OTC Industrial Manual, 1994' Moody's OTC Unlisted Manual, Dun & Bradstreet's Million Dollar Directory, 1994; Herman Miller Annual Reports, 1989-1991. SECTION 4 - PRIMARY ECONOMIC IMPACTS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY ANALYSIS 4-11 ------- LIMITATIONS Several qualifications of the results presented in this section need to be made. A single market for homogeneous output is assumed in the partial equilibrium analysis. However, there may be some regional trade barriers which would protect producers. Furthermore, the analysis assumes that plants with the highest per unit emission control costs are marginal post-control. This assumption will cause the impacts presented above to be overstated since market impacts are determined by the costs of marginal plants. Some plants may find that the price increase resulting from regulations make it profitable to expand production. This would occur if a firm found its post-control incremental unit costs to be smaller than the post-control market prices. Expansion by these firms would result in smaller decreases in output and smaller increases in prices than predicted by our analysis. For instance, plants that emit less than the major source threshold do not have to comply with the standard. They enjoy price increases without incurring of compliance costs. Furthermore, some plants may choose to alter their production mix of different foam grades, choosing to drop altogether or reduce certain foam grades and increase production of other grades requiring and/or emitting less HAP. Plants unaffected by the standard may increase production to produce those foam grades whose production is reduced or dropped by other producers. We have also noted that the estimated primary impacts depend on the parameters of the partial equilibrium model. The results of the sensitivity analyses presented in Appendix C, which are based on alternative estimates of demand and supply elasticity, show slightly less adverse impacts on domestic producers in the case of lower elasticities and slightly more adverse impacts in the case of more elastic supply and demand estimates. Also note that in Appendix D, we report the results of a sensitivity analysis which alters assumptions about the assignments of the control technologies for the slabstock industry. SECTION 4 - PRIMARY ECONOMIC IMPACTS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY ANALYSIS 4-12 ------- SUMMARY Under the MACT Floor and Regulatory Alternative 1, we estimate that slabstock foam prices will increase by about 2.2 percent and output is will fall by about 1 percent. However, under both of these alternatives, the value of slabstock shipments will increase by about 1 percent. One to two slabstock plant closures are predicted under the MACT floor and one to three are predicted under Regulatory Alternative 1. We predict more adverse impacts under Regulatory Alternative 2, with slabstock prices increasing by about 3.8 percent and output declining by about 1.86 percent. One to four plant closures are possible. Finally, because emission control costs are very small relative to the financial resources of the affected producers examined, they should not find it difficult to raise the capital necessary to finance the purchase and installation of emission controls. For the molded foam sector, the estimated economic impacts of the NESHAP are relatively small. Predicted price increases and reductions in domestic output are approximately 1 percent or less under all three regulatory alternatives. The estimated value of shipments for the molded foam segment increases under all three alternatives. No plant closures are expected under the MACT Floor or Alternative 2. However, three closures are predicted under Regulatory Alternative 1. SECTION 5 SECTION 4 - PRIMARY ECONOMIC IMPACTS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY ANALYSIS 4-13 ------- SECONDARY ECONOMIC IMPACTS INTRODUCTION This section presents estimates of the secondary economic impacts that would result from the implementation of the alternative NESHAPs. Secondary impacts include changes in employment, energy use, foreign trade and regional impacts. LABOR IMPACTS The estimated labor impacts associated with the NESHAP are based on the results of the partial equilibrium analyses of the two segments of the flexible polyurethane foam industry. These impacts depend primarily on the estimates of reduction in domestic production reported earlier in Section 4.31 Note that changes in employment due to the operation and maintenance of control equipment have been omitted from this analysis due to lack of data. Also, the estimated employment impacts reported below do not include potential employment gains in industries which produce substitute commodities that might benefit from reduced flexible slabstock and flexible molded foam production or employment losses in industries supplying inputs to the foam industry. Thus, the changes in employment estimated in this section reflect only the direct employment losses due to reductions in domestic production of flexible slabstock and flexible molded foam. Table 5-1 presents estimates of employment losses for the two industry sectors. As Table 5-1 indicates, estimated job losses in the slabstock industry segment range from 95 jobs (in Regulatory Alternative 1) to 164 jobs (in Regulatory Alternative 2). As 31 More specifically, we estimate employment impacts by assuming that labor use per unit of output will remain constant when the quantity of output changes. Production worker hours per dollar of output was calculated from 1992 Census of Manufactures. See Appendix B for a more detailed discussion. SECTION 5 - SECONDARY ECONOMIC IMPACTS 5-2 ------- expected, the estimated employment losses in Regulatory Alternative 1 are slightly less than those predicted for the MACT Floor. This less severe labor impact occurs primarily because smaller reductions in output are expected to occur as a result of the implementation of Regulatory Alternative 1 than from the implementation of the MACT Floor. As a result, the associated labor impacts are less. Table 5-1 also displays labor impacts for the molded foam industry segment. The estimated labor reductions associated with the implementation of the MACT floor are quite small, with only two production job losses expected. We estimate the implementation of Regulatory Alternatives 1 and 2 to result in 23 and 31 job losses, respectively, in the molded foam segment. Table 5-1 FLEXIBLE POLYURETHANE FOAM INDUSTRY ESTIMATED EMPLOYMENT REDUCTIONS Industry Segment Slabstock (jobs) (% reduction) Molded (jobs) (% reduction) MACT Floor 99 1.12 2 0.04 Regulatory Alternative 1 95 1.08 23 0.42 Regulatory Alternative 2 164 1.86 31 0.56 Note: Estimates do not include potential employment gains due to operating and maintaining emission controls. As noted above, our estimates of employment impacts are driven by the estimates of output reductions and plant closures reported in Section 4. This means that the estimated employment impacts reflect the worst-case assumptions adopted in the analysis for the same reasons provided earlier. ENERGY USE IMPACTS SECTION 5 - SECONDARY ECONOMIC IMPACTS 5-3 ------- The approach we employ to estimate reductions in energy use is similar to the approach employed to estimate labor impacts. Again, these impacts depend primarily on the estimated reductions in domestic output reported earlier in Section 4. Note that the changes reported below do not account for the potential increases in energy use due to operating and maintaining emission control equipment or possible changes in production times for reformulated foam products. This omission is due to lack of data. Table 5-2 presents changes in the use of energy for the two industry segments. The change in the use of energy by the slabstock foam industry ranges from 1.08 percent (in Regulatory Alternative 1) to 1.86 percent (in Regulatory Alternative 2). Given the magnitude of national production impacts on the molded sector, smaller energy use reductions are expected for the molded foam industry under all three regulatory alternatives. Energy impacts associated with the implementation of the MACT Floor are estimated to be only 0.04 percent. We expect energy impacts under Regulatory Alternatives 1 and 2 to be 0.42 percent and 0.56 percent respectively. FOREIGN TRADE IMPACTS Other factors being the same, the implementation of the NESHAP will raise the production costs of domestic foam manufacturers relative to foreign producers. In an industry with no barriers to international trade, this would cause U.S. imports to increase and U.S. exports to decrease. However, as discussed previously, due to the nature of the product, foreign trade in flexible polyurethane foam is negligible. It is a large volume product with very little value per unit volume. High transportation costs relative to foam value makes long distance foam transport financially prohibitive. As such, flexible polyurethane foam industries in other countries produce foam to satisfy their domestic demand. Due to the absence of international trade in flexible polyurethane foam, no significant foreign trade impacts are anticipated. Table 5-2 SECTION 5 - SECONDARY ECONOMIC IMPACTS 5-4 ------- ESTIMATED ENERGY USE REDUCTIONS Industry Segment Slabstock(1000$94) (% reduction) Molded (1000$94) (% reduction) MACT Floor 424.73 1.12 8.00 0.04 Regulatory Alternative 1 409.57 1.08 98.00 0.42 Regulatory Alternative 2 703.03 1.86 134.00 0.56 Note: Estimates do not include potential employment gains due to operating and maintaining emission controls. REGIONAL IMPACTS Although it is not possible to identify the specific locations of plants that might close as a result of the alternatives, our analysis of slabstock plant locations revealed that, apart from a few exceptions, foam production facilities tend to be geographically dispersed. As a result, we do not anticipate any significant regional impacts as a result of the implementation of the proposed NESHAP. The flexible polyurethane foam industry is non-labor intensive. Both large and small facilities need only a small number of employees to operate the foam production line. Foam production is, for the most part, an automated process requiring only monitoring once the production process is underway. As such, labor utilization at production plants are small relative to regional labor supplies. Therefore, even in cases where plant closures are predicted, no significant labor or regional impacts are expected because employment impacts are likely to be small relative to total local employment. LIMITATIONS The estimates of the secondary impacts associated with the NESHAP are based on changes in market equilibria predicted by the partial equilibrium models of the two affected markets. Accordingly, the caveats discussed earlier in Section 4 for the SECTION 5 - SECONDARY ECONOMIC IMPACTS 5-5 ------- primary impacts apply as well to the estimates of secondary impacts. Also, we note that the estimates of employment impacts are based on the average value of production per worker hour for SIC 3086. Labor productivity in the slabstock and molded foam segments could differ from the four-digit industry-wide level. As noted earlier, the estimates of employment impacts do not include potential employment gains due to operating and maintaining emission control equipment or employment gains in the manufacturing of substitute products. Similarly, the estimates we report exclude potential indirect employment losses in industries that supply inputs to the flexible polyurethane foam industries and employment gains in industries producing substitute products. In short, the reported estimates of employment impacts include only direct production job losses in the flexible polyurethane slabstock and molded industries. SUMMARY The estimated secondary economic impacts of the alternative NESHAP are generally small for the molded foam segment of the industry because only small reductions in industry output are expected for this sector. Impacts range from 0.04 percent to 0.56 percent under the three regulatory alternatives. There are no expected foreign trade impacts because there is virtually no international trade in flexible polyurethane molded foam. No significant impacts on regional economies are expect- ed. The estimated secondary economic impacts of the alternative NESHAPs are somewhat larger for the slabstock segment of the industry because larger reductions in domestic production are predicted for this industry segment. Estimated employment and energy impacts range from 1.08 percent to 1.86 percent under the three regulatory alternatives. As with the molded foam sector, there exists virtually no international trade in slabstock foam. As such, no significant trade impacts are expected. Also, no significant regional impacts are expected. SECTION 5 - SECONDARY ECONOMIC IMPACTS 5-6 ------- SECTION 6 POTENTIAL SMALL BUSINESS IMPACTS SECTION 5 - SECONDARY ECONOMIC IMPACTS 5-7 ------- INTRODUCTION The Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA) requires an analysis of the potential effects of proposed regulations on small business entities. Specifically, the RFA requires that a determination be made as to whether the subject regulation will significantly impact a substantial number of small entities. Firms are classified as small based on company-wide employment rather than plant employment. The Small Business Administration (SBA) classifies firms in the flexible polyurethane foam industry (SIC 3086) as small if total company-wide employment is less than 500 employees.32 This definition is consistent with recent guidance from EPA's General Counsel on the interpretation of the Small Business Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act of 1996.33 We describe below the results of two analyses designed to assess the potential impacts of the regulatory alternatives on small businesses. In the first analysis, we estimate the impact that the alternatives will have on the costs of differently sized plants. In the second analysis, we predict, under a worst-case scenario, plant closures by plant size. First, however, we explain how we matched model plants with firms to determine small business status. MATCHING MODEL PLANTS WITH FIRMS As noted above, firms are classified as small entities based on company-wide rather than plant-level employment. However, because plants in the flexible polyurethane foam industry are so numerous, the analysis in this report is conducted using model plants rather than actual plants whose identities can be linked to specific 32 See13CFR121. 33 See EPA (1996). SECTION 6: POTENTIAL SMALL BUSINESS IMPACTS 6-2 ------- firms. Nonetheless, it is possible to draw some conclusion about the small business status of affected facilities by matching model plants to companies responding to the Industry Questionnaire 1993, issued under Section 114 of the CAAA. The questionnaire reports company-wide employment and plant-level production for each facility included in the survey. By matching annual production levels, it is possible to assign probable model plant types to each facility included in the survey. Because company-wide employment is reported for plants included in the sample, it is possible to estimate the percent of each model plant type that satisfies the small business criteria (i.e., company-wide employment under 500). Table 6-1 shows the results of the matching exercise. For example, we estimate that ten (50.0 percent) of model plant type MP1 slabstock facilities could be owned by small businesses, based on the 500 employee criterion. Note that we cannot determine the number of HP1 molded foam plants that could be small entities. This model plant type is characterized by production technology (high-pressure mixhead) and not production level. Also, note that some companies may own both slabstock and molded facilities. In these cases, it is likely that the parent company is too large to be considered a small business. Based on our estimates, 71 possible small businesses could be affected by the NESHAP, 18 slabstock and 53 molded foam producers. Recall that molded foam facilities of the LP1 model plant type will not require controls and are therefore not included in the count of affected small businesses. We urge caution in interpreting the results reported in Table 6-1. First, we assume that respondents to Industry Questionnaire 1993 interpreted "total employment" as total company-wide employment rather than total plant employment. Fewer plants would satisfy the small business employment criterion if respondents reported plant employment. Second, some of the molded foam plants assigned to LP1, LP2 and LP3 SECTION 6: POTENTIAL SMALL BUSINESS IMPACTS 6-3 ------- could be HP1 type plants. This issue is significant since the HP1 plants are not expected to incur any costs as a result of the regulatory alternatives. Finally, the results for molded foam plants are based on a sample of plants. 34 Table 6-1 ESTIMATED SMALL BUSINESS STATUS OF MODEL PLANTS Model Plant Number Slabstock MP1 MP2 MP3 MP4 MP5 Molded HP1 LP1 LP2 LP3 Estimated Small Busi- nesses (Percent) 50.0 26.7 6.7 0.0 7.7 a 76.9 80.0 22.2 Estimated Small Businesses (Count) 10 7 1 0 0 a 84 43 10 Source: Responses to Industry Questionnaire 1993, issued under Section 114 of the CAAA. Notes: a The HP1 model plant is characterized by production technology (high-pressure mixhead) and not production level. As a result, the percent of these plants that could be small businesses cannot be estimated. IMPACTS ON COSTS BY PLANT SIZE The EPA estimates that about 234 plants produce molded foam nationwide, however, the questionnaire includes only 47 plants. Data from the questionnaire were used to determine the percentage of small businesses in each model plant classification. These percentages were then used to extrapolate to the 234 plants to estimate the number (count) of small businesses in each model plant classification. SECTION 6: POTENTIAL SMALL BUSINESS IMPACTS 6-4 ------- Compliance costs associated with the implementation of the regulatory alternatives will increase the costs of producing flexible polyurethane foam. To place these costs in perspective, we compute annualized compliance costs as a percent of baseline revenues for each model plant.35 Tables 6-2 and 6-3 show the results of the analysis for the slabstock and molded foam segments, respectively. For example, under the MACT Floor, the smallest slabstock model plant, MP1, is expected to incur average annualized compliance costs of about 1.59 percent of estimated baseline revenues, which is the largest average compliance costs relative to baseline revenues.36 The relative difference between compliance costs as a percent of revenues for model plant MP1 and the next largest plant, MP2, is larger for Regulatory Alternatives 1 and 2 than for the MACT Floor. Table 6-2 IMPACT ON COSTS BY PLANT SIZE: SLABSTOCK Regulatory Alternative MACT Floor Alternative 1 Alternative 2 Model Plant Number MP1 MP2 MP3 MP4 MP5 MP1 MP2 MP3 MP4 MP5 MP1 MP2 MP3 MP4 MP5 Number of Plants 19 28 14 11 6 19 28 14 11 6 19 28 14 11 6 Average Change in Costs (% of Revenues) 1.59 0.92 0.67 0.46 0.76 1.84 0.65 0.29 0.22 0.57 2.29 1.02 0.54 0.54 0.52 The capital costs associated with compliance costs are amortized over a 10 year equipment life at a 10 percent real private discount rate. MP1 produces less than 100 tons of foam product annually. See Appendix A. SECTION 6: POTENTIAL SMALL BUSINESS IMPACTS 6-5 ------- SECTION 6: POTENTIAL SMALL BUSINESS IMPACTS 6-6 ------- Table 6-3 IMPACT ON COSTS BY PLANT SIZE: MOLDED Regulatory Alternative MACT Floor Alternative 1 Alternative 2 Model Plant Number HP1 LP1 LP2 LP3 HP1 LP1 LP2 LP3 HP1 LP1 LP2 LP3 Number of Plants 27 109 54 44 27 109 54 44 27 109 54 44 Average Change in Costs (% of Revenues) 0.0000 0.0000 0.0088 0.0328 0.0000 0.0000 0.7983 -0.0815 0.0000 0.0000 -0.2641 0.1891 As Table 6-3 indicates, the smallest mold foam model plant, LP1, is not expected to incur any compliance costs as a result of the regulatory alternative. The same is true for model plant HP1, which could be very small or large.37 The largest molded foam model plant, LP3, is expected to incur the highest compliance costs relative to baseline revenues under the MACT Floor.38 Recall that MP1 is characterized by production process and not plant size. 38 Average compliance costs are negative for LP3 under Regulatory Alternative 1 and negative for LP2 under Alternative 2 because of savings associated with control strategies. SECTION 6: POTENTIAL SMALL BUSINESS IMPACTS 6-7 ------- Table 6-1 shows that the smallest slabstock model plant, MP1, is more likely to be operated by a small business than the other slabstock model plants. Accordingly, the finding in Table 6-2 that this model plant is also likely to incur the highest relative compliance costs suggests potential adverse impacts on small businesses. However, we note that the results reported in Table 6-2 and 6-3 are average compliance costs for each model plant. Because of variations in the costs of control technologies, compliance costs vary within model plant categories, even for a given regulatory alternative. Also, affected plants will be able to offset at least some compliance costs by passing price increases to their customers. In fact, the slabstock price increases we predict in Section 4 are sufficient to offset average compliance costs, even for the smallest model plants. 39 PREDICTED PLANT CLOSURES BY PLANT SIZE Earlier in Section 4, we used our partial equilibrium model to predict plant closures caused by the implementation of the regulatory alternatives. Tables 6-4 and 6-5 report, respectively, predicted plant closures by model plants for the slabstock and molded foam segments. For example, our analysis predicts that 0 to 2 of the 19 model plants MP1 will close Table 6-4 PREDICTED PLANT CLOSURES: SLABSTOCK Regulatory Alternative MACT Floor Model Plant Number MP1 MP2 MP3 MP4 MP5 Number of Plants 19 28 14 11 6 Predicted Closures Oto2 Oto1 0 0 0 This does not mean that all plants of a given model plant type will be able to offset all compliance costs through higher prices. Again, compliance costs vary within plant types due to differences in costs of selected control technologies. SECTION 6: POTENTIAL SMALL BUSINESS IMPACTS 6-8 ------- Alternative 1 Alternative 2 MP1 MP2 MP3 MP4 MP5 MP1 MP2 MP3 MP4 MP5 19 28 14 11 6 19 28 14 11 6 Oto3 Oto1 0 0 0 Oto3 1 0 0 0 Table 6-5 PREDICTED PLANT CLOSURES: MOLDED Regulatory Alternative MACT Floor Alternative 1 Alternative 2 Model Plant Number HP1 LP1 LP2 LP2 HP1 LP1 LP2 LP3 HP1 LP1 LP2 LP3 Number of Plants 27 109 54 44 27 109 54 44 27 109 54 44 Predicted Closures 0 0 0 0 0 0 3 0 0 0 0 0 and 0 to 1 of the 28 model plants MP2 will close under the MACT Floor40. There is insufficient data to determine the exact ownership of the plants that may close. It is estimated that half of the MP1 plants, 27 percent of the MP2 plants, and 15 percent of the other slabstock model plants are owned by small businesses. Without facility-specific data, The range is dependent upon the assignment of control technology to the model plants, with the least-cost technology yielding the lower value of the range and the highest-cost technology yielding the upper value of the range. SECTION 6: POTENTIAL SMALL BUSINESS IMPACTS 6-9 ------- the analysis cannot determine if these impacts will occur at small businesses owning these facilities. Table 6-5 shows that no plant closures are predicted for molded foam producers under the MACT Floor or Regulatory Alternative 2. Also, no plant closures are predicted for the smallest model plants, LP1, for Regulatory Alternative 1. Recall that these small plants are not expected to incur compliance costs under any of the regulatory alternatives. The finding that the smallest slabstock plants are most likely to close under the regulatory alternatives provides the potential adverse impacts on small businesses. Given that any estimate of closures is based upon worst-case assumptions41, it is likely that these impacts are overestimated and the affect on small businesses will be minimal. REFERENCE EPA (1996). Memorandum from Jonathan Z. Cannon, EPA General Counsel, to the Administrator, April 2. 41 See Section 4 for a discussion of these assumptions. SECTION 6: POTENTIAL SMALL BUSINESS IMPACTS 6-10 ------- SECTION 7 SOCIAL COSTS AND ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY Estimates of the social (economic) costs associated with the implementation of the alternative NESHAPs for the flexible polyurethane slabstock and flexible polyurethane molded foam industry segments are presented below in this section of the report. We also present an analysis of the economic efficiency of the regulatory alternatives. SOCIAL COSTS OF EMISSION CONTROLS: CONCEPTUAL ISSUES Air quality regulations affect society's economic well-being by causing a reallocation of productive resources within the economy. Specifically, resources are allocated to the production of cleaner air and away from other goods and services that could otherwise be produced. Accordingly, the social, or economic, costs of emission controls can be measured as the value that society places on those goods and services not produced as a result of resources being diverted to the production of improved air quality. According to economic theory, the conceptually correct valuation of these costs requires the identification of society's willingness to be compensated for these foregone consumption opportunities that would otherwise be available.42'43 42 Willingness to be compensated is the appropriate measure of economic costs, given the convention of measuring benefits as willingness to pay. Under this convention, the potential to compensate those members of society bearing the costs associated with a policy change is compared SECTION 6: POTENTIAL SMALL BUSINESS IMPACTS 6-11 ------- In the discussion that follows, we distinguish between emission control costs and the social or economic costs associated with the regulatory alternatives. The former are measured simply as the annualized capital and annual operating and maintenance costs of controls under the assumption that all affected plants install controls. As noted above, economic costs reflect society's willingness to be compensated for foregone consumption opportunities. Estimates of emission control costs will correspond to the conceptually correct measure of economic costs only if the following conditions hold: • Marginal plants affected by an alternative standard must be able to pass forward all emission control costs to buyers through price mark-ups without reducing the quantity of goods and services demanded in the market. • The prices of emission control resources (e.g., pollution control equipment, alternative materials, and labor) used to estimate costs must correspond to the prices that would prevail if these factors were sold in competitive markets. • The discount rate employed to compute the present value of future costs must correspond to the appropriate social discount rate. • Emission controls do not affect the prices of goods imported to the domestic economy. Market Adjustments A plant is marginal if it is among the least efficient producers in the market and, as a result, the level of its costs determine the post-control equilibrium price. A marginal plant can pass on to buyers the full burden of emission control costs only if with the potential willingness of gainers to pay for benefits. See Mishan (1971). 43 These costs are often referred to as "Social Costs," as well as economic costs. SECTION 7 - SOCIAL COSTS AND ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY 7-2 ------- demand is perfectly inelastic. Otherwise, consumers will reduce quantity demanded when faced with higher prices. If this occurs, estimated control costs will overstate the economic costs associated with a given air quality standard. The emission control costs estimates do not reflect any market adjustments that are likely to occur as affected plants and their customers respond to higher post-control production costs. As a result, the estimates of economic costs presented later in this section will differ from the emission control costs to reflect estimates of such market adjustments. Markets for Emission Control Resources Other things being the same, estimated emission control costs will overstate the economic costs associated with an alternative air quality standard if the estimates are based on factor prices (e.g., emission control equipment prices and wage rates) which reflect monopoly profits earned in resource markets. Monopoly profits represent a transfer from buyers to sellers in emission control markets, but do not reflect true resource costs. We note that some of the available emission control technologies are patented. To the extent that the patents confer monopoly power, the estimates of compliance costs used in this analysis are higher than they would be if emission controls were sold in competitive markets. If this is the case, the analysis overstates true economic costs. The Social Discount Rate The estimates of annualized emission control costs presented earlier in this report were computed by adding the annualized estimates of capital expenditures associated with the purchase and installation of emission control equipment to estimates of annual operating and maintenance costs. Capital expenditures were annualized using a 7 percent discount rate. The private cost of capital is appropriate SECTION 7 - SOCIAL COSTS AND ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY 7-3 ------- for estimating how producers adjust supply prices in response to control costs.44 In order to estimate the economic costs associated with the alternative NESHAPs, an appropriate measure of the social discount rate should be used in the amortization schedule. 44 In other words, a discount rate reflecting the private cost of capital to affected firms should be used in analyses designed to predict market adjustments associated with emission control costs. The private cost of capital, assumed to be 10 percent in this analysis, is higher than the 7 percent social discount rate because it reflects the greater risk faced by individual producers relative to the risk faced by society at large. SECTION 7 - SOCIAL COSTS AND ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY 7-4 ------- There is considerable debate regarding the use of alternative discounting procedures and discount rates to assess the economic benefits and costs associated with public programs.45 The approach adopted here is a two-stage procedure recommended by Kolb and Scheraga (1990). First, annualized costs are computed by adding annualized capital expenditures (over the expected life of emission controls) and annual operating costs. Capital expenditures are annualized using a discount rate that reflects a risk-free marginal return on investment.46 This discount rate, which is referred to below as the social cost of capital, is intended to reflect the opportunity cost of resources displaced by invest- ments in emissions controls. Kolb and Scheraga (1990) recommend a range of 5 to 10 percent for this rate. We adopt a midpoint value of 7.0 percent in this analysis.47 Second, the present value of the annualized stream of costs should be computed using a consumption rate of interest which is taken as a proxy for the social rate of time preference. This discount rate, which is referred to below as the social rate of time preference, measures society's willingness to be compensated for postponing current consumption to some future date. Kolb and Scheraga (1990) argue that the consumption rate of interest probably lies between 1 and 5 percent. We do not, however, present estimates of the present value of the costs associated with the NESHAP in this report. The resulting estimates of the present value of the economic costs associated with the alternative NESHAPs can be compared with estimates of the present value of corresponding benefits of the regulatory alternatives. The social rate of time preference should be employed to discount the future stream of estimated benefits. 45 See Lind, et al. (1982) fora more detailed discussion of this debate. 46 The risk-free rate is appropriate if the NESHAP, as a program, does not add to the variance of the return on society's investment portfolio. 47 The 7 percent discount rate is also consistent with recent OMB recommendations. SECTION 7 - SOCIAL COSTS AND ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY 7-5 ------- OTHER COSTS ASSOCIATED WITH NESHAP It should be recognized that the estimates of costs reported later in this section do not reflect all costs that might be associated with the NESHAP. Examples of these include some administrative, monitoring, and enforcement costs (AME), and transition costs. AME costs may be borne by directly affected firms and by different government agencies. These latter AME costs, which are likely to be incurred by state agencies and EPA regional offices, for example, are reflected neither in the estimates of emission control costs, nor in the estimates of economic costs. However, our estimates do include administrative and monitoring costs incurred by affected firms. Transition costs are also likely to be associated with the alternative standards. Analyses described in previous sections of this report, for example, predict that some plants will close because of emission control costs. This will cause some individuals to suffer transition costs associated with temporary unemployment and affected firms to incur shutdown costs. These transition costs are not reflected in the cost estimates reported later in this section. CHANGES IN ECONOMIC SURPLUS AS A MEASURE OF COSTS As was noted earlier, the willingness to be compensated for foregone consumption opportunities is taken here as the appropriate measure of the costs associated with the alternative NESHAPs. In this case, compensating variation is an exact measure of willingness to be compensated. In practice, however, compensating variation is difficult to measure; consequently, the change in economic surplus associated with the air quality standard is used as an approximation to compensating variation. SECTION 7 - SOCIAL COSTS AND ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY 7-6 ------- The degree to which a change in economic surplus coincides with compensating variation as a measure of willingness to be compensated depends on whether the surplus change is measured in an input market or a final goods market. The surplus change is an exact measure of compensating variation when it is measured in an input market, but it is an approximation when measured in a final goods market.48 The direction of the bias in the approximation of compensating variation when the surplus change is measured in a final goods market depends on whether affected parties realize a welfare gain or suffer a welfare loss, but in either case, the bias is likely to be small.49 Affected firms (and their customers) will suffer a welfare loss as the result of the implementation of emission controls. In this case, the change in economic surplus will exceed compensating variation, the exact measure of willingness to be compensated.50 We note, however, that this study measures surplus changes in input markets. ESTIMATES OF SOCIAL COSTS Estimates of the annualized total social costs associated with the NESHAP are reported in Tables 7-1 and 7-2 (for a social cost of capital equal to 7.0 percent). For the slabstock segment, estimates of total annual costs of the NESHAP are $11.86 million under the MACT Floor, $7.18 million under Regulatory Alternative 1, and $10.92 million under Regulatory Alternative 2. For the molded foam industry, estimates of total annual costs are much smaller. They are $190 thousand under the MACT Floor, $60 thousand under Regulatory Alternative 1, and $710 thousand under Regulatory Alternative 2. 48 See Just, Hueth, and Schmitz (1982) fora more detailed discussion. 49 See Willig (1974). 50 See Appendix B for a detailed, technical description of the methods employed to compute changes in economic surplus. SECTION 7 - SOCIAL COSTS AND ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY 7-7 ------- We measure economic costs as net losses in economic surplus. Tables 7-1 and 7-2 show how losses in surplus are distributed among consumers, domestic producers and society at large. The latter is referred to as "residual" surplus in the tables. The loss in consumer surplus includes higher outlays for foam plus a dead weight loss due to foregone consumption. As Tables 7-1 and 7-2 indicate, consumers in each market suffer a loss in surplus. These losses are due mostly to higher expenditures on slabstock and molded foam. We compute the loss in producer surplus as annualized monitoring and emission control costs incurred by plants remaining in operation plus the dead weight loss in surplus due to reduced output less increased revenue due to higher post-control prices. The estimated losses in producer surplus reported in Tables 7-1 and 7-2 are negative, meaning that producers would realize a net gain in economic surplus. This occurs because higher post-control market prices more than offset emission control costs. Table 7-1 SLABSTOCK FOAM INDUSTRY ESTIMATES OF ANNUALIZED ECONOMIC COSTS Regulatory Alternative MACT Floor Regulatory Alt. 1 Regulatory Alt. 2 Loss in Consumer Surplus (MM$94) 39.05 37.64 65.12 Loss in Producer Surplus (MM$94) -19.03 -20.83 -37.97 Loss in Residual Surplus (MM$94) -8.16 -9.63 -16.24 Loss in Surplus Total (MM$94) 11.86 7.18 10.92 SECTION 7- SOCIAL COSTS AND ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY 7-8 ------- Table 7-2 MOLDED FOAM INDUSTRY ESTIMATES OF ANNUALIZED ECONOMIC COSTS Regulatory Alternative MACT Floor Regulatory Alt. 1 Regulatory Alt. 2 Loss in Consumer Surplus (MM$94) 0.81 8.99 12.21 Loss in Producer Surplus (MM$94) -0.46 -6.56 -8.44 Loss in Residual Surplus (MM$94) -0.16 -2.38 -3.05 Loss in Total Surplus (MM$94) 0.19 0.06 0.71 Surplus losses to society at large are computed as "residual" adjustments to account for differences in private and social discount rates and transfer effects of taxes. The estimates of changes in producer surplus reflect a 10 percent real private rate on emission control capital costs. Recall that social costs are discounted at a 7.0 percent real rate.51 We note that the distribution of economic costs between consumers and domestic producers depends, in part, on the way we have constructed the post-control supply curve. As explained earlier, we have assumed that plants with the highest emission control costs (per unit of output) are marginal in the post-control market. This assumption is worst case in that it results in large increases in prices (relative to an alternative assumption that plants with high control costs are not marginal), thus shifting the cost burden to consumers and away from plants that continue to operate in the 51 Since the loss in producer surplus measures the burden of the alternative borne by producers, we calculate it using the private cost of capital. SECTION 7- SOCIAL COSTS AND ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY 7-9 ------- post-control market. Any alternative construction of the post-control supply curve would result in smaller price increases and shift a larger share of economic costs away from consumers to domestic producers. In other words, smaller price increases would reduce the economic rent realized by domestic producers in the post-control market. Earlier, we explained that economic costs differ from emission control costs. Recall that the latter are computed simply as annualized capital costs plus annual operating and maintenance costs, assuming that all plants install controls. Table 7-3 reports estimates of annualized emission control and monitoring costs. These estimates are higher than the economic costs reported in Tables 7-1 and 7-2. Recall that the estimates of economic costs reflect market adjustments to higher prices, while the estimates of emission control costs do not. Table 7-3 ESTIMATES OF THE ANNUALIZED EMISSION CONTROL COSTS (Millions of 1994 dollars) Regulatory Alternative MACT Floor Regulatory Alternative 1 Regulatory Alternative 2 Slabstock Foam 12.14 7.53 11.46 Molded Foam 0.19 0.07 0.73 NOTE: Estimates are computed as annualized capital costs plus annual operating, monitoring and maintenance costs, assuming all plants continue to operate after controls are installed. Capital costs are annualized at a 7 percent discount rate. ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY A regulatory alternative is economically efficient if it generates larger net benefits (benefits minus costs) than other alternatives. A dominant alternative generates the SECTION 7 - SOCIAL COSTS AND ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY 7-10 ------- same or larger total emission reductions at a lower cost than any other alternative. Since we presume that larger emission reductions yield higher benefits, a dominant alternative is economically efficient relative to all other alternatives (since it produces the same or larger benefits at a lower cost). An inferior alternative, on the other hand, generates the same or smaller emission reductions at a higher cost than at least one other alternative. An inferior alternative is economically inefficient because at least one other alternative generates higher net benefits. We use the estimates of economic costs (reported in Tables 7-1 and 7-2) for the efficiency analysis. Also, our estimates of emission reductions include lower emission reductions due to controls as well as adjustments for predicted plant closures. Specifically, we assume that emissions fall to zero at plants predicted to close. Table 7-4 reports the results of the analysis. None of the three regulatory alternatives is clearly dominant. However, the MACT Floor is inferior to both Alter- native 1 and Alternative 2. The MACT Floor generates lower annual emission reductions at a higher annual cost than either Alternative 1 or Alternative 2. Therefore, we conclude that the MACT floor is economically inefficient relative to these two regulatory alternatives. Note that Alternative 2 generates larger emission reductions than Alternative 1, but at higher costs. As a result, the information provided in Table 7-4 is not sufficient to evaluate the economic efficiency of Alternative 2 relative to Alternative 1. Alternative 2 would be efficient relative to Alternative 1 if the additional benefits associated with higher emission reductions (5,647 tons annually) exceed its incremental costs ($4.39 million annually). SECTION 7 - SOCIAL COSTS AND ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY 7-11 ------- Table 7-4 ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY OF REGULATORY ALTERNATIVES Regulatory Alternative MACT Floor Regulatory Alternative 1 Regulatory Alternative 2 Annual Economic Costs ($1994MM) 12.05 7.24 11.63 Annual Emission Reduction (tons) 10,105 13,642 19,289 NOTE: Estimates include costs and emission reductions for both the slabstock and molded foam industry segments. One final comment on why this analysis is worthwhile. Some of the estimated economic impacts associated with Alternatives 1 and 2 are more adverse than for the MACT Floor (e.g., more closures) even though the MACT Floor gives rise to higher social costs. This occurs because, compared with the MACT Floor, Alternatives 1 and 2 impose higher compliance costs on marginal (higher cost) plants, but more than offsetting lower costs on non-marginal plants. Thus, while the MACT Floor is inferior, some of its economic impacts are less severe than those for Alternatives 1 and 2. In other words, some of the distributional impacts of the MACT floor are less severe than those of the other regulatory alternatives. REFERENCES SECTION 7- SOCIAL COSTS AND ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY 7-12 ------- Just, R.E., D.L. Hueth and A. Schmitz (1982). Applied Welfare Economics and Public Policy, Prentice Hall, Inc., Englewood Cliffs, NJ. Kolb, J.A. and J.D. Scheraga (1990). "Discounting the Benefits and Costs of Environmental Regulations." Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, Vol. 9, No. 3, Summer. Lind, R.C., et_al., (1982). Discounting for Time and Risk in Energy Policy, Resources for the Future, Inc., Washington, DC. Mathtech (1985a). Corporate Income Taxes, Social Costs, and Distributional Impacts: Implications for ElA's. Prepared for the Office of Air Quality Planning and Stan- dards, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. Mathtech (1985b). Estimated Control Costs and Social Costs: Implications of Investment Tax Credits for ElA's. Prepared for the Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. Mishan, E.J. (1971). Cost-Benefit Analysis, Praeger Publishers, Inc., New York. Willig, R.D. (1976). "Consumer Surplus Without Apology," American Economic Review, 66, No. 4, September, 589-97. SECTION 7 - SOCIAL COSTS AND ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY 7-13 ------- APPENDIX A AFFECTED PLANTS AND EMISSION CONTROL COSTS This appendix describes the model plants and the estimates of emission control and monitoring costs used in this study. AFFECTED PLANTS The model plants used in the analyses are characterized by product type (either molded or slabstock foam) and production quantity. Tables A-1 and A-2 describe the model plants used in the molded and slabstock sector analyses. Table A-1 MOLDED FOAM MODEL PLANT BASELINE PARAMETERS Foam production range (tons/yr) Average foam production (tons/yr) Number of facilities represented Model plant emissions (tons/yr) HP1 0-15,000 3,331 27 2.09 LP1 0-99 26 109 5.29 LP2 100-499 308 54 19.81 LP3 >499 2,718 44 28.66 Source: EC/R Incorporated (1996a). Table A-2 SLABSTOCK FOAM MODEL PLANT BASELINE PARAMETERS MP1 MP2 MP3 MP4 MP5 SECTION 7- SOCIAL COSTS AND ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY 7-14 ------- Foam production range (tons/yr) Average foam production (tons/yr) Number of facilities represented Model plant (a) emissions (tons/yr) Model plant (b) emissions (tons/yr) 0-3.9 2,000 19 64.19 59.19 4.0-7. 9 6,000 28 174.16 169.16 8.0-11.9 10,000 14 339.42 334.42 12.0-15.9 13,750 11 343.93 338.93 >15.9 19,000 6 388.53 383.53 Source: EC/R Incorporated (1996a). MOLDED FOAM There are four molded foam production model plants. One of these model plants represents larger molded foam facilities using high-pressure mixheads (HP1), primarily to produce automobile seats. The remaining three model plants represent smaller producers that use low-pressure mixheads (LP1, LP2, LP3) to produce a variety of foam products. Model plant impacts and compliance control costs were developed for a number of technologies to bring the following source types into compliance: • mixhead flushing, • mold release agents, • repair adhesive. Emission Control Costs Model plant impacts were developed for four technologies to reduce or eliminate mixhead flushing emissions: work practices for Regulatory Alternative 1; and non-HAP flushes, high pressure mixheads, and self-cleaning mixheads for Regulatory Alternative 2. Table A-3 presents a summary of the model plant costs and emission reductions for mixhead flushing compliance. For all regulatory alternatives, the level of control for mold release agents is the prohibition of the use of HAP-based mold release agents, resulting in a 100 percent emission reduction. Model plant impacts were developed for three technologies that APPENDIX A: AFFECTED PLANTS AND EMISSION CONTROL COSTS A-2 ------- can achieve this level: reduced volatile organic compound (VOC) mold release agents, naphtha-based mold release agents, and water-based mold release agents. A summary of mold release agent model plant impacts is contained in Table A-4. Table A-3 MOLDED FOAM MODEL PLANT IMPACTS FOR TECHNOLOGIES TO REDUCE MIXHEAD FLUSHING HAP EMISSIONS Technology Non-HAP Flush Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) High-Pressure Mixhead Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) Self-Cleaning Mixhead Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) Solvent Recovery System Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) HP1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 LP1 0 (920) 5.14 a 658,125 163,815 5.14 31,871 225,688 34,938 5.14 6,797 47,250 23,412 3.86 6,073 LP2 0 (3,823) 19.69 a 658,125 146,107 19.69 7,420 225,688 17,231 19.69 875 47,250 10,131 14.77 686 LP3 0 (8,065) 21.31 a 658,125 112,535 21.31 5,281 225,688 (16,341) 21.31 a 47,250 (15,048) 15.98 a $are 1994 dollars. aCost effectiveness not calculated because net annualized cost is a negative quantity (cost savings). Sources: EC/R Incorporated (1996a and 1996b). For all regulatory alternatives, the level of control for repair adhesives is also the prohibition of the use HAP-based adhesives, resulting in a 100 percent emission reduction. Model plant impacts were developed for three technologies that can achieve APPENDIX A: AFFECTED PLANTS AND EMISSION CONTROL COSTS A-3 ------- this level: hot-melt adhesives, water-based adhesives, and hydrofuse adhesives. Table A-5 provides a summary of repair adhesive model plant impacts. APPENDIX A: AFFECTED PLANTS AND EMISSION CONTROL COSTS A-4 ------- Table A-4 MOLDED FOAM MODEL PLANT IMPACTS FOR TECHNOLOGIES TO REDUCE MOLD RELEASE AGENT HAP EMISSIONS Technology Reduced-VOC Agent Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) Naphtha-Based Agent Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) Water-Based Agent Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) HP1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 LP1 0 50 0.15 337 05 375 0.15 2,500 0 48 0.15 323 LP2 0 39 0.12 328 0 293 0.12 2,439 0 38 0.12 315 LP3 0 1,023 6.00 171 0 7,599 6.00 1,267 0 981 6.00 163 $are 1994 dollars. Sources: EC/R Incorporated (1996a and 1996b). In calculating nationwide regulatory impacts, only major sources of HAP will be subject to the Foam Production NESHAP. Since the high-pressure molded model plant and the smallest low-pressure molded model plant have emissions below the major source thresholds, it was assumed that the facilities represented by these model plants would not be affected by the NESHAP. Therefore, nationwide regulatory alternative impacts are based on the costs and emission reductions associated with the production facilities represented by model plants LP2 and LP3. APPENDIX A: AFFECTED PLANTS AND EMISSION CONTROL COSTS A-5 ------- Table A-5 MOLDED FOAM MODEL PLANT IMPACTS FOR TECHNOLOGIES TO REDUCE HAP EMISSIONS FROM THE USE OF FOAM ADHESIVES Technology Hot-Melt Adhesive Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) Hydrofuse Adhesive Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) Water-Based Adhesive Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) HP1 6,804 6,377 2.09 3,047 5,670 738 2.09 353 0 (854) 2.09 a LP1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 LP2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 LP3 6,804 1,869 1.35 1,384 5,670 1,001 1.35 5,281 0 (97) 1.35 a $are 1994 dollars. aCost effectiveness not calculated because net annualized cost is a negative quantity (cost savings). Sources: EC/R Incorporated (1996a and 1996b). For affected model plants, a compliance technology (corresponding to the above tables) is assigned to each source type. Table A-6 gives the distribution of technologies to model plants and source types used to estimate the molded foam nationwide regulatory alternative costs. Since different technologies (with different costs) can bring a source type into compliance, nationwide impacts are dependent upon the compliance technology chosen by the plant. APPENDIX A: AFFECTED PLANTS AND EMISSION CONTROL COSTS A-6 ------- Table A-6 DISTRIBUTION OF TECHNOLOGIES USED TO ESTIMATE THE MOLDED FOAM NATIONWIDE REGULATORY ALTERNATIVE COSTS BY MODEL PLANT Emission Source/Technology Mixhead Flush Reg Alt 1 Solvent recovery Reg Alt II Non-HAP flush HP mixheads Mold Release Agents All Regulatory Alternatives Reduced VOC agents Naphtha-based agents Water- based agents Repair Adhesives All Regulatory Alternatives Hot-melt adhesives Water- based adhesives Number of Facilities with the Assigned Technology LP2 54 54 0 18 18 18 N/A N/A LP3 44 35 9 15 14 15 22 22 Sources: EC/R Incorporated (1996a and 1996b). While Table A-6 shows the assumed distributions of control technologies adopted by model plants for each emission source separately, it does not give the distribution for combinations of control technologies. For example, under Alternative 2, 35 of 44 LP3 type model plants are assumed to adopt non-HAP flush to control mixhead flush and 15 to adopt reduced VOC agents to control mold release agents. However, Table A-6 does not show how many LP3 plants adopt non-HAP flush and reduced VOC agents. For the economic impact analysis, we assume that model plants adopt combinations of control technologies consistent with the proportions shown in Table A-6. For example, we assume that 34 percent (15 of 44) of the 35 plants using non-HAP flush also use APPENDIX A: AFFECTED PLANTS AND EMISSION CONTROL COSTS A-7 ------- reduced VOC agents. We note, however, that the estimated impacts presented in this report are not sensitive to assumptions about the distribution of combinations of control technologies as long as some plants adopt the most costly combinations. The economic impacts are driven by the level of control costs facing the highest cost producers, and not the number of high cost producers. Table A-7 SLABSTOCK FOAM MODEL PLANT COSTS FOR STORAGE/UNLOADING Regulatory Alternative 1 and MACT Floor Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) Regulatory Alternative 2 Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) MP1 8,220 1,673 0.083 20,218 4,110 873 0.000095 9,186,710 MP2 12,330 1,756 0.247 9,700 8,220 1,740 0.000475 3,673,295 MP3 4,110 438 0.494 887 N/A $are 1994 dollars. Sources: EC/R Incorporated (1996a and 1996b). SLABSTOCK FOAM MODEL PLANTS There are five basic model plants for slabstock foam, each representing a range of production. Each basic model plant is separated into facilities that use MeCI2 as an equipment cleaner, and facilities that do not (e.g. MP1a uses MeCb as an equipment cleaner and MP1 b does not). Model plant impacts and compliance control costs were APPENDIX A: AFFECTED PLANTS AND EMISSION CONTROL COSTS A-8 ------- developed for a number of technologies to bring the following source types into compliance: • storage/unloading, • equipment cleaning, • equipment leaks, • HAP auxiliary blowing agent (ABA) emissions. The MACT floor level of control for storage and unloading of both TDI and HAP ABA is an equipment standard that requires either a vapor balance system to return the displaced HAP vapors to the tank truck or rail car, or a carbon canister through which emissions must be routed prior to being emitted to the atmosphere. The subsequent regulatory alternatives do not contain more stringent requirements. The model plant impacts are based on the installation of vapor balance. The slabstock foam production model plant costs for storage/unloading emission control are provided in Table A-7. There are no costs for model plants 4 and 5 because all TDI and MeCb storage tanks at these model plants are assumed to be controlled at baseline. The MACT floor level of control for equipment cleaning is the complete elimination of HAP emissions. The subsequent regulatory alternatives do not contain more stringent requirements. Model plant costs were developed for the use of non-HAP equipment cleaners. These costs are shown in Table A-8. The amount of MeCb used to clean the equipment is consistent for all model plants. Therefore, the impacts shown in Table A-8 are applicable for all model plants. The MACT floor level of control for equipment leaks was determined to be sealless pumps for TDI transfer pumps. The first regulatory alternative adds a unique LDAR program for HAP ABA components. Since Regulatory Alternative 2 does not allow the emission of any HAP ABA (which, in effect, prohibits the use of MeCb or any other HAP as an ABA), this alternative only contains the MACT floor requirement for APPENDIX A: AFFECTED PLANTS AND EMISSION CONTROL COSTS A-9 ------- TDI pumps. Table A-9 shows model plant MACT floor level impacts. Table A-10 shows model plant Regulatory Alternative 1 impacts. APPENDIX A: AFFECTED PLANTS AND EMISSION CONTROL COSTS A-10 ------- Table A-8 SLABSTOCK FOAM MODEL PLANT COSTS FOR EQUIPMENT CLEANING EQUIPMENT CLEANING IMPACTS FOR ALL REGULATORY SCENARIOS FOR ALL MODEL PLANTS Capital Cost Annual Cost Emission Reduction Cost Effectiveness $0 ($275) 5.0 tons/yr N/A $are 1994 dollars. Sources: EC/R Incorporated (1996a and 1996b). Table A-9 MACT FLOOR SLABSTOCK FOAM MODEL PLANT EQUIPMENT LEAK IMPACTS Model Plant 1 2,3,4,5 Capital Cost ($1994) 5,000 N.A. Annual Cost ($/yr) 932 N.A. Emission Reduction (ton/yr) 0.33 N.A. Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) 2,800 N.A. $are 1994 dollars. Sources: EC/R Incorporated (1996a and 1996b). Table A-10 ALTERNATIVE 1 SLABSTOCK FOAM MODEL PLANT EQUIPMENT LEAK IMPACTS Model Plant 1 2 3 4 5 Capital Cost ($1994) 12,544 7,544 7,544 7,544 7,431 Annual Cost ($/yr) 7,245 5,980 5,980 5,980 5,810 Emission Reduction (ton/yr) 1.2 1.0 1.0 1.0 0.8 Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) 6,038 5,980 5,980 5,980 7,263 APPENDIX A: AFFECTED PLANTS AND EMISSION CONTROL COSTS A-11 ------- Source: EC/R Incorporated (1996c). There are three levels of control for HAP ABA emissions. The MACT Floor and Regulatory Alternative 1 have emission limits based on formulation limitations. Applying the two sets of formulation limitations to the product mix of the model plants results in the emission reductions shown in Table A-11. The second regulatory alternative requires the complete elimination of HAP ABA emissions. Table A-11 MODEL PLANT HAP ABA REGULATORY ALTERNATIVE EMISSION REDUCTIONS Model Plant Baseline HAP ABA Emissions (tons/yr) 1 2 3 4 5 55.0 165.0 330.0 335.0 380.0 HAP ABA Emission Reduction (tons/yr) MACT Floor 31.3 93.8 184.0 195.9 220.4 Reg Alt 1 35.9 111.7 220.7 235.7 266.0 Reg Alt 2 55.0 165.0 330.0 335.0 380.0 Sources: EC/R Incorporated (1996a, 1996b, and 1996d). For each level of control, model plant impacts were developed for several technologies. While there are numerous technologies available to reduce HAP ABA emissions, the effectiveness of individual technologies is widely disputed within the foam industry. Therefore, the engineering contractor made assumptions, based on their knowledge of the industry, regarding the technologies that could be used to meet each of the three HAP ABA levels of control. Table A-12 shows the technologies assumed for each regulatory alternative level. APPENDIX A: AFFECTED PLANTS AND EMISSION CONTROL COSTS A-12 ------- TableA-12 TECHNOLOGIES CAPABLE OF ACHIEVING HAP ABA REGULATORY ALTERNATIVE LEVELS Regulatory Alternative MACT Floor Level Regulatory Alternative 1 Regulatory Alternative 2 Technology Chemical alternatives Carbon dioxide as an ABA Acetone as an ABA Variable pressure foaming Forced cooling Carbon dioxide as an ABA Acetone as an ABA Variable pressure foaming Forced cooling Carbon dioxide plus chemical alternatives Acetone as an ABA Variable pressure foaming Forced cooling plus chemical alternatives Source: EC/R Incorporated (1996a). As can be seen in Table A-12, some technologies can be used to meet more than one level of control. In these cases, it was assumed that the technologies would only be used to the degree necessary to meet the level of the regulatory alternative. In other words, although variable pressure foaming can be used to totally eliminate the use of HAP ABA, it was assumed that at the MACT floor level, the amount of MeCb allowed would still be used and emitted. Tables A-13 through A-17 provide model plant costs associated with the compliance technologies found in Table A-12. APPENDIX A: AFFECTED PLANTS AND EMISSION CONTROL COSTS A-13 ------- TableA-13 SLABSTOCK FOAM MODEL PLANT COSTS FOR CHEMICAL ALTERNATIVES HAP ABA EMISSION REDUCTION MACT Floor Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) Model Plant Costs MP1 31,725 54,523 31.3 1,742 MP2 31,725 151,713 93.8 1,617 MP3 31,725 274,276 184.0 1,491 MP4 31,725 335,202 195.9 1,711 MP5 31,725 378,997 220.4 1,720 $are 1994 dollars. Sources: EC/R Incorporated (1996a and 1996b). TableA-14 SLABSTOCK FOAM MODEL PLANT COSTS FOR CARDIO HAP ABA EMISSION REDUCTION MACT Floor Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) Regulatory Alternative 1 Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) Regulatory Alternative 2 - CarDio plus Chemical Alternatives Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) Model Plant Costs MP1 31,725 54,523 31.3 1,742 429,300 66,354 37.9 1,751 461,025 84,163 55 1,530 MP2 31,725 151,713 93.8 1,617 429,300 23,254 113.7 204 461,025 27,660 165 168 MP3 31,725 274,276 184.0 1,491 429,300 (42,403) 222.7 a 461,025 (29,666) 330 a MP4 31,725 335,202 195.9 1,711 429,300 (38,631) 237.7 a 461,025 17,561 335 52 MP5 31,725 378,997 220.4 1,720 429,300 (43,559) 268.0 a 461,025 16,227 380 43 APPENDIX A: AFFECTED PLANTS AND EMISSION CONTROL COSTS A-14 ------- $are 1994 dollars. a. Cost effectiveness not calculated because net annualized cost is a negative quantity (cost savings). Sources: EC/R Incorporated (1996a and 1996b). APPENDIX A: AFFECTED PLANTS AND EMISSION CONTROL COSTS A-15 ------- TableA-15 SLABSTOCK FOAM MODEL PLANT COSTS FOR ACETONE ABA EMISSION REDUCTION MACT Floor Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) Regulatory Alternative 1 Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) Regulatory Alternative 2 Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) Model Plant Costs MP1 194,000 35,121 31.3 1,122 194,000 32,455 37.9 856 194,000 25,306 55 460 MP2 31,725 151,713 93.8 1,617 429,300 23,254 113.7 204 194,000 (22,633) 165 a MP3 31,725 274,276 184.0 1,491 429,300 (42,403) 222.7 a 194,000 (99,520) 330 a MP4 31,725 335,202 195.9 1,711 429,300 (38,631) 237.7 a 194,000 (101,750) 335 a MP5 31,725 378,997 220.4 1,720 429,300 (43,559) 268.0 a 194,000 (121,840) 380 a $are 1994 dollars. a. Cost effectiveness not calculated because net annualized cost is a negative quantity (cost savings). Sources: EC/R Incorporated (1996a and 1996b). APPENDIX A: AFFECTED PLANTS AND EMISSION CONTROL COSTS A-16 ------- TableA-16 SLABSTOCK FOAM MODEL PLANT COSTS FOR VARIABLE PRESSURE FOAMING HAP ABA EMISSION REDUCTION MACT Floor Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) Regulatory Alternative 1 Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) Regulatory Alternative 2 Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) Model Plant Costs MP1 4,500,000 774,400 31.3 24,741 4,500,000 769,120 37.9 20,293 4,500,000 755,440 55 13,735 MP2 4,500,000 724,400 93.8 7,723 4,500,000 708,480 113.7 6,231 4,500,000 667,486 165 4,047 MP3 4,500,000 652,240 184.0 3,545 4,500,000 621,280 222.7 2,790 4,500,000 535,531 330 1,623 MP4 4,500,000 642,720 195.9 3,281 4,500,000 609,280 237.7 2,563 4,500,000 531,546 335 1,587 MP5 4,500,000 623,120 220.4 2,827 4,500,000 585,040 268.0 2,183 4,500,000 495,679 380 1,305 $are 1994 dollars. Sources: EC/R Incorporated (1996a and 1996b). APPENDIX A: AFFECTED PLANTS AND EMISSION CONTROL COSTS A-17 ------- TableA-17 SLABSTOCK FOAM MODEL PLANT COSTS FOR FORCED COOLING HAP ABA EMISSION REDUCTION MACT Floor Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) Regulatory Alternative 1 Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) Regulatory Alternative 2 Forced Cooling plus Chemical Alternatives Capital Investment ($) Annual Cost ($/yr) Emission Reduction (tons/yr) Cost Effectiveness ($/ton) Model Plant Costs MP1 1,000,000 162,500 31.3 5,192 1,000,000 157,220 37.9 4,148 1,031,725 167,441 55 3,044 MP2 2,000,000 305,180 93.8 3,254 2,000,000 289,260 113.7 2,544 2,031,725 308,350 165 1,869 MP3 2,000,000 243,300 184.0 1,322 2,000,000 212,340 222.7 953 2,031,725 227,636 330 690 MP4 2,000,000 243,418 195.9 1,243 2,000,000 209,978 237.7 883 2,031,725 217,033 335 648 MP5 2,000,000 237,310 220.4 1,076 2,000,000 199,230 268.0 743 2,031,725 207,189 380 545 $are 1994 dollars. Sources: EC/R Incorporated (1996a, 1996b and 1996c). Table A-18 shows the distribution of ABA emission reduction technologies used to estimate slabstock foam nationwide regulatory alternative costs by model plant. Note, Appendix D contains sensitivity analyses of regulatory impacts when technology combination assumptions are modified. APPENDIX A: AFFECTED PLANTS AND EMISSION CONTROL COSTS A-18 ------- TableA-18 DISTRIBUTION OF ABA EMISSION REDUCTION TECHNOLOGIES USED TO ESTIMATE THE SLABSTOCK FOAM NATIONWIDE REGULATORY ALTERNATIVE COSTS BY MODEL PLANT Technology MACT Floor CarDio Acetone VPF Forced Cooling Chem Alts Reg Alt I CarDio Acetone VPF Forced Cooling Reg Alt II CarDio + Chem Alts Acetone VPF Forced Cooling + Chem Alts Number of Facilities Using the Technology MP1 4 1 0 2 12 13 3 0 3 10 3 0 6 MP2 9 1 0 4 14 18 4 0 6 15 3 1 9 MP3 4 1 0 3 6 6 3 0 5 5 2 1 6 MP4 4 1 0 3 3 5 2 0 4 3 2 2 4 MP5 1 0 2 2 1 1 1 2 2 1 1 2 2 Sources: EC/R Incorporated (1996a and 1996b). MONITORING COSTS In addition to the emission control costs described earlier in this appendix the estimated economic impacts presented in this report include the effects of monitoring, inspection, recordkeeping and reporting costs (MIRR) at affected plants. Total annual MIRR costs are estimated for each industry segment as 10 percent of nationwide annual emission control costs. Annual MIRR costs per plant are estimated as APPENDIX A: AFFECTED PLANTS AND EMISSION CONTROL COSTS A-19 ------- nationwide MIRR costs for the industry segment divided by the number of affected plants in the industry segment.52 REFERENCES EC/R Incorporated (1996a). Technical memorandum from Phil Norwood and Amanda Williams to David Svendsgaard (EPA/OAPQS), January 26. EC/R Incorporated (1996b). Technical memorandum from Phil Norwood to Jeffrey Sassin (Mathtech), February 18. EC/R Incorporated (1996c). Technical memorandum from Phil Norwood to David Svensgaard and Lisa Conner (EPA/OAQPS), March 26. EC/R Incorporated (1996d). Technical memorandum from Phil Norwood to Jeffrey Sassin (Mathtech), June 6. 52 EC/R Incorporated (1996d). APPENDIX A: AFFECTED PLANTS AND EMISSION CONTROL COSTS A-20 ------- APPENDIX B TECHNICAL DESCRIPTION OF ANALYTICAL METHODS This technical appendix provides detailed descriptions of the analytical methods employed to conduct the following analyses: • Partial equilibrium analysis (i.e., computing post-control price, output and trade impacts). • Estimating changes in economic surplus. • Labor and energy impacts. • Capital availability. We also present the baseline values used in the partial equilibrium analysis. PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS The partial equilibrium analysis requires the completion of four tasks. These tasks are: • Specify market demand and supply. • Estimate the post-control shift in market supply. • Compute the impact on market quantity. • Compute the impact on market price. • Predict plant closures. APPENDIX A: AFFECTED PLANTS AND EMISSION CONTROL COSTS A-21 ------- The following description of the partial equilibrium model is fully general in that it includes a foreign sector. Recall, however, that trade in flexible foam is negligible. Accordingly, we set foreign supply (net imports) at zero for this study. APPENDIX B: TECHNICAL DESCRIPTION OF ANALYTICAL METHODS 6-2 ------- Market Demand and Supply Baseline or pre-control equilibrium in a market is given by: Qd = aPE (B.1) Qd = pPy (B.2) Q* = pPy (B.3) Qd = Qd + Q* = Q (B.4) where, Q = output; P = price; e = demand elasticity; y = supply elasticity; a, p and p are constants; Subscripts d and s reference demand and supply, respectively; and, Superscripts d and f reference domestic and foreign supply, respectively. The constants a, p and p are computed such that the baseline equilibrium price is normalized to one. Note that the market specification above assumes that domestic and foreign supply elasticities are the same. Market Supply Shifts Supply price for a model plant will increase by an amount just sufficient to equate the net present value of the investment and operation of the control equipment to zero. Specifically, APPENDIX B: TECHNICAL DESCRIPTION OF ANALYTICAL METHODS 6-3 ------- [ (OQ) - (V+D) ] (l-t)+D _ o O — .K where C is the change in the supply price; Q is output; V is a measure of annual operating and maintenance control costs. t is the marginal corporate income tax rate; S is the capital recovery factor; D is annual depreciation (we assume straight-line depreciation); k is the investment cost of emissions controls. kS-D V+D C = Q(l-t) + Q Solving for C yields the following expression: Estimates of k and V were obtained from EPA (1991). The variables, D, I, and S are computed as follows: D = k/T (B.7) and S = r(1+r)T/((1+r)T-1) (B.8) where r is the discount rate or cost of capital faced by producers; T is the life of emission control equipment. Solving for P in Equation (B.2) yields the following expression for the baseline inverse market supply function for domestic producers. APPENDIX B: TECHNICAL DESCRIPTION OF ANALYTICAL METHODS B-4 ------- P = (Qd/p)1/y (B.9) Emission control costs will raise the supply price of the ith model plant by C\ (as computed in Equation (B.6)). The aggregate domestic market supply curve, however, does not identify the supply price for individual plants. Accordingly, we adopt the worst-case assumption that model plants with the highest after-tax per unit control costs are marginal in the post-control market. Specifically, we write the post-control supply function as P = (Qd/p)1/Y+C(Ci,qi) (B.10) where q\ is the total output of all model plants of type i. The function C(Ci,qi) shifts segments of the pre-control domestic supply curve vertically by Cj. The width or horizontal distance of each segment is qj. The resulting segmented post-control domestic supply curve is illustrated in Figure B-1 as 82, compared with pre-control supply Si.53 53 The supply curves in Figure B-1 are drawn as linear functions for ease of exposition. Because the supply curves are specified as Cobb-Douglas, they are log-linear. APPENDIX B: TECHNICAL DESCRIPTION OF ANALYTICAL METHODS 6-5 ------- Impact on Market Price and Quantity The impacts of the alternative standards on market output are estimated by solving for post-control market equilibrium and then comparing that output level, Q2, to the pre-control output level, Qi. Because post-control domestic supply is segmented, a special iterative algorithm was developed to solve for post-control market equilibrium. The algorithm first searches for the segment in the post-control supply function at which equilibrium occurs and then solves for the post-control market price that clears the market. Since the market clearing price occurs where demand equals post-control domestic supply plus foreign supply, the algorithm simultaneously solves for the following post-control variables. APPENDIX B: TECHNICAL DESCRIPTION OF ANALYTICAL METHODS 6-6 ------- • Equilibrium market price. • Equilibrium market quantity. We assess the market impacts of control costs by comparing baseline values to post-control values for each of the variables listed above. We also report the change in the dollar value of shipments by domestic producers. This value, AVS, is given by AVS = P2«Qs - P Q* ^ r-J -L H where PI and P2 are, respectively, pre- and post-control market equilibrium prices. Plant Closures We predict that any plant will close if its post-control supply price is higher than the post-control equilibrium price. Post-control supply prices are computed by Equation (B.10). We round fractions of plant closures to the nearest integer. APPENDIX B: TECHNICAL DESCRIPTION OF ANALYTICAL METHODS 6-7 ------- CHANGES IN ECONOMIC SURPLUS The shift in market equilibrium will have impacts on the economic welfare of three groups: • Consumers. • Producers. • Society at large. The procedure for estimating the welfare change for each group is presented below. The total change in economic surplus, which is taken as an approximation to economic costs, is computed as the sum of the surplus changes for the three groups. Change in Consumer Surplus Consumers will bear a dead weight loss associated with the reduction in output. This loss represents the amount over the pre-control price that consumers would have been willing to pay for the eliminated output. This surplus change is given by: i x (Q/a)1/E dQ - P± • (Q±-Q2 In addition, consumers will have to pay a higher price for post-control output. This surplus change is given by: (P2-Pi)-Q2 The total impact on consumer surplus, ACS, is given by (B.12) plus (B.13). Specifically, APPENDIX B: TECHNICAL DESCRIPTION OF ANALYTICAL METHODS 6-8 ------- ACS = Jx (Q/a)1/E dQ - P. Q. + P9Q9 Q This change, ACS, includes losses of surplus incurred by foreign consumers. In this report we are only concerned with domestic surplus changes. We have no method for identifying the marginal consumer as foreign or domestic. To estimate the change in domestic consumer surplus we assume that total consumer surplus is split between foreign and domestic consumers in the same proportion that sales are split between foreign and domestic consumers in the pre-control market. That is, the change in domestic consumer surplus, ACSd, is: ACS While ACS is a measure of the consumer surplus change from the perspective of the world economy, ACSd represents the consumer surplus change from the perspective of the domestic economy. Change in Producer Surplus To examine the effect on producers, output can be divided into two components: • Output eliminated as a result of controls. • Remaining output of controlled plants. The total change in producer surplus is given by the sum of the two components. Note that post-tax measures of surplus changes are required to estimate the impacts of controls on producers' welfare. The post-tax surplus change is computed by APPENDIX B: TECHNICAL DESCRIPTION OF ANALYTICAL METHODS B-9 ------- multiplying the pre-tax surplus change by a factor of (1-t) where t is the marginal tax rate. As a result, every one dollar of post-tax loss in producer surplus will be associated with a complimentary loss of t/(1-t) dollars in tax revenues. Output eliminated as a result of control costs causes producers to suffer a dead-weight loss in surplus analogous to the dead-weight loss in consumer surplus. The post-tax dead-weight loss is given by: -J 1^ dQ '1-t' L -L. "— J Plants remaining in operation after controls realize a welfare gain of P2 - PI on each unit of output, but incur a per unit welfare loss of Cj. Thus, the post-tax loss in producer surplus for m model plant types remaining in the market is (P1-P2)QS I (1-t) The total post-tax change in producer surplus, APS, is given by the sum of (B.16) and (B. 17). Specifically, APS = dQ + (1-t) Recall that we are interested only in domestic surplus changes. For this reason we do not include the welfare gain experienced by foreign producers due to higher prices. This procedure treats higher prices paid for imports as a dead-weight loss in APPENDIX B: TECHNICAL DESCRIPTION OF ANALYTICAL METHODS B-10 ------- consumer surplus. Higher prices paid to foreign producers represent a transfer from the perspective of the world economy, but a welfare loss from the perspective of the domestic economy. Residual Effect on Society The changes in economic surplus, as measured above, must be adjusted to account for two effects which cannot be attributed specifically to consumers and producers. These two effects are caused by tax impacts and differences between private and social discounts rates. Two adjustments for tax impacts are required. First, per unit control costs C\, which are required to predict post-control market equilibrium, reflect after-tax control costs. The true resource costs of emissions controls, however, must be measured on a pre-tax basis. For example, if after-tax control costs exceed pre-tax control costs, C\ overstates the true resource costs of controlling emissions. A second tax-related adjustment is required because changes in producer surplus have been reduced by a factor of (1-t) to reflect the after-tax welfare impacts of emissions control costs on affected plants. As was noted earlier, a one dollar loss in pre-tax producer surplus imposes an after-tax burden on the affected plant of (1-t) dollars. In turn, a one dollar loss in after-tax producer surplus causes a complimentary loss of t/(1-t) dollars in tax revenues. A second adjustment is required because of the difference between private and social discount rates. The rate used to shift the supply curve reflects the private discount rate (or the marginal cost of capital to affected firms). This rate must be used to predict the market impacts associated with emission controls. The economic costs of the NESHAP, however, must be computed at a rate reflecting the social cost of APPENDIX B: TECHNICAL DESCRIPTION OF ANALYTICAL METHODS B-11 ------- capital. This rate is intended to reflect the social opportunity cost of resources displaced by investments in emission controls.54 The adjustment for the two tax effects and the social cost of capital, which we refer to as the residual change in surplus, ARS, is given by: m ARS = -I (Ci-pci)qi + APS«[t/(l-t)] where pq = per unit cost of controls for model plant type i, computed as in (B.5) with t=0 and r=social cost of capital. The first term on the right-hand-side of (B.20) adjusts for the difference between pre- and post-tax differences in emission control costs and for the difference between private and social discount rates. Note that these adjustments are required only on post-control output. The second term on the right-hand-side of (B.19) is the complimentary transfer of the sum of all post-tax producer surplus. Total Economic Costs The total economic costs, EC, is given by the sum of changes in consumer and producer surplus plus the change in residual surplus. Specifically, EC = ACSd + APS + ARS (B.20) LABOR AND ENERGY IMPACTS 54 See Section 7 for a more detailed discussion of this issue. APPENDIX B: TECHNICAL DESCRIPTION OF ANALYTICAL METHODS B-12 ------- Our estimates of the labor and energy impacts associated with the alternative standards are based on input-output ratios and estimated changes in domestic production. Labor Impacts Labor impacts, measured as the number of jobs lost due to domestic output reductions, are computed as: AL = 2000 where AL is the change in employment, U is the production worker hours per dollar of output, and all else is as previously defined. The number 2000 is used to translate production worker hours into jobs (i.e., we assume a 2000 hour work year). Energy Impacts We measure the energy impacts associated with the alternative standards as the reduction in expenditures on energy inputs due to output reductions. The method we employ is similar to the procedure described above for computing labor impacts. Specifically, AE = EP Q -< II where AE is the change in expenditures on energy inputs, E! is the baseline expenditure on energy input per dollar output and all else is as previously defined. APPENDIX B: TECHNICAL DESCRIPTION OF ANALYTICAL METHODS B-13 ------- BASELINE INPUTS The partial equilibrium model described above requires, as inputs, data on the characteristics of affected plants and baseline values for variables and parameters that characterize each market. The characteristics of affected plants have been described earlier in Appendix A. These include the number of plants by model type and a measure of output for each model plant. Appendix A also reports estimates of capital and annual emission control costs. Table B-1 reports the baseline values of variables and parameters for each market segment. The baseline prices of slabstock foam are taken from Table 3-5, converted to a weight measure using the average of the densities in the table, and adjusted to 1994 dollars using the GDP implicit deflator. The molded foam price is given at $2.35 per pound in current dollars and adjusted to 1994 dollars using the GDP implicit deflator. Baseline domestic output in each market is computed as the sum of production at all domestic plants (see Appendix A for production rates at slabstock and molded foam plants). The demand and supply elasticities in Table B-1 are assumed values used in the base case analysis reported in the text of this report. We assess the sensitivity of the estimated impacts to demand elasticity by reporting in Appendix D results based on "low" and "high" estimates. We use a marginal tax rate of 25 percent to assess the impacts of emission controls. We adopt a 10 percent private discount rate (real marginal cost of capital) and a 7.0 percent social discount rate. The expected life of emission control equipment is 10 years. Finally, the values for labor hours per unit of output (l_i) and energy use per unit of output (Ei) are computed from the data reported in Tables 3-14, 3-15 and 3-16 and adjusted to 1994 dollars using the GDP implicit deflator. Recall that these data are avail- APPENDIX B: TECHNICAL DESCRIPTION OF ANALYTICAL METHODS B-14 ------- able at the 4-digit SIC code level. Both slabstock and molded foam products are included in SIC code 3086. For this reason, U and EI are the same in both market segments. CAPITAL AVAILABILITY ANALYSIS Pre- and post-control values of the following financial measures are compared in the capital availability analyses: • Net income/assets. • Long-term debt/long-term debt plus equity. Pre-Control Financial Measures Pre-control measures of net income and net income/assets are computed by averaging data for the period 1991 through 1993 where these data are available. The long-term debt ratio is computed from 1993 data, or the most recent year available. APPENDIX B: TECHNICAL DESCRIPTION OF ANALYTICAL METHODS B-15 ------- Table B-1 BASELINE INPUTS Variable/Parameter Price (P0a d . Domestic Output (Qs ) Supply Elasticity (e) Demand Elasticity (y) Tax Rate (t) Private Discount Rate (r) Social Discount Rate Equipment Life (T)c Labor (L0d Energy (E^6 MARKET Slabstock $2,812 611,250 10.0 -0.5 0.25 0.1 0.07 10 .01025 0.022 Molded $4,700 228,995 10.0 -0.5 0.25 0.1 0.07 10 .01025 0.022 Notes: a Dollars (1992) per kilogram (wet weight). b Tons per year. c Years. d Production worker hours per dollar of output. e Energy expenditure per dollar of output. Then, pre-control values are estimated by: i) n = 1993 Z ni/4 1=1991 (B.23) ii) r iii) I where n 1=1991 Il993/(ll993 + 61993) average net income (B.24) (B.25) APPENDIX B: TECHNICAL DESCRIPTION OF ANALYTICAL METHODS B-16 ------- rij = net income in year i r = average return on assets a\ = assets in year i I = long-term debt ratio I1993 = long-term debt in 1993 61993 = equity in 1993 Post-Control Values To determine the impact of controls, an estimate of the cost of controls is made. In order to get an idea of the steady-state cost, an annualized cost is used. The annualized cost, AC, for a plant is: AC = V + kS (B.26) where the variables are as defined previously. However, affected firms will realize an increase in revenue, AR, because of higher post-control prices. We compute this value as AR = (P2-Pi)-q (B.27) where P2 - PI is the price change and q is the firm's output. Annualized costs and capital costs are estimated for each model plant type. For each establishment, post-control measures are given by: APPENDIX B: TECHNICAL DESCRIPTION OF ANALYTICAL METHODS B-17 ------- 1993 ni+AR-AC pn = Z ——7 1=1991 1993 (n.-AR-AC)/(a.+k) 1 1 z 1=1991 _ P " Il993+ei993+k where pn = post-control average net income AC = annualized cost for the company pr = post-control return on assets k = capital cost for the company pi = post-control long-term debt ratio APPENDIX B: TECHNICAL DESCRIPTION OF ANALYTICAL METHODS B-18 ------- APPENDIX C SENSITIVITY ANALYSES: DEMAND AND SUPPLY ELASTICITIES INTRODUCTION This appendix presents the results of sensitivity analyses that explore the degree to which the results presented earlier in this report are sensitive to estimates of demand and supply elasticities. SUPPLY AND DEMAND ELASTICITY The "base case" results presented earlier in this report are based on a demand elasticity of -0.5 and a supply elasticity of 10.0 for both molded and slabstock foam. Below, we report results for "low" and "high" elasticity cases. These alternative cases use the following elasticities values: •Low demand elasticity: -0.25 for molded and slabstock foam. •Low supply elasticity: 5.00 for molded and slabstock foam. •High demand elasticity: -1.00 for molded and slabstock foam. •High supply elasticity: 50.00 for molded and slabstock foam. The greater the elasticity of demand and supply (in absolute value), the greater the change in market clearing quantity in response to a given change in price. Therefore, we expect that when we use higher demand and supply elasticities in the partial e- quilibrium analysis, the reduction in market output will be greater than in the base case. APPENDIX C: SENSITIVITY ANALYSES: DEMAND AND SUPPLY ELASTICITIES C-1 ------- Similarly, when we use lower elasticities, we expect the change in market quantity to be smaller, relative to the base case. Tables C-1 through C-4 present estimates of the primary economic impacts associated with the alternative forms of the NESHAP for the molded and slabstock industry segments in the case of low and high elasticities. Tables C-1 and C-2 report results based on low elasticities and Tables C-3 and C-4 report results based on high elasticities. Note that these results do not take into consideration the sensitivity analysis conducted in Appendix D for the slabstock segment of the industry. These results assume the distribution of higher-cost control technology. For the molded foam segment, plant closures and market output impacts are unchanged or less severe under all regulatory alternatives for the low elasticity case. The three predicted closures under Regulatory Alternative I mid-elasticity assumptions are reduced to two closures when a low elasticity is assumed. For the slabstock segment, plant closures and market impacts are also less severe or unchanged under the assumptions of low elasticities. The four predicted closures under Regulatory Alternative 2 mid-elasticity assumptions are reduced to one closure under low elasticity assumptions. For the molded and slabstock markets, impacts on domestic output, value of domestic shipments, and energy and employment are all more severe under the assumptions of "high" elasticities. Predicted plant closures increase from three under the base case to six for the molded sector under Regulatory Alternative 1. Under the MACT Floor, slabstock closures increase from two under the base case to four under the high elasticity case. Slabstock plant closures under the high elasticity case also increase for Regulatory Alternatives 1 and 2. APPENDIX C: SENSITIVITY ANALYSES: DEMAND AND SUPPLY ELASTICITIES C-2 ------- Table C-1 SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS: ESTIMATED PRIMARY IMPACTS ON THE SLABSTOCK FOAM MARKET WITH LOW ELASTICITIES Regulatory Alternative MACT Floor Alternative 1 Alternative 2 Price (%) 2.66 3.68 4.02 Market Output (%) -0.65 -0.90 -0.98 Value of Domestic Shipments (%) ($MMa) 1.99 2.75 3.00 34.19 47.23 51.63 Plant Closures 2 3 1 a1994$ Note: Results based on demand elasticity of-0.25 and supply elasticity of 5.0 and a distribution of higher-cost control technologies. Table C-2 SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS: ESTIMATED PRIMARY IMPACTS ON THE MOLDED FOAM MARKET WITH LOW ELASTICITIES Regulatory Alternative MACT Floor Alternative 1 Alternative 2 Price (%) 0.07 0.84 1.14 Market Output (%) -0.02 -0.21 -0.28 Value of Domestic Shipments (%) ($MMa) 0.06 0.63 0.85 0.60 6.75 9.17 Plant Closures 0 2 0 a1994$ Note: Results based on demand elasticity of -0.25 and supply elasticity of 5.0. APPENDIX C: SENSITIVITY ANALYSES: DEMAND AND SUPPLY ELASTICITIES C-3 ------- Table C-3 SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS: ESTIMATED PRIMARY IMPACTS ON THE SLABSTOCK FOAM MARKET WITH HIGH ELASTICITIES Regulatory Alternative MACT Floor Alternative 1 Alternative 2 Price (%) 2.35 2.27 3.03 Market Output (%) -2.30 -2.22 -2.94 Value of Domestic Shipments (%) ($MMa) 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Plant Closures 4 4 7 a1994$ Note: Results based on demand elasticity of -1.0 and supply elasticity of 50.0 and a distribution of higher-cost control technologies. Table C-4 SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS: ESTIMATED PRIMARY IMPACTS ON THE MOLDED FOAM MARKET WITH HIGH ELASTICITIES Regulatory Alternative MACT Floor Alternative 1 Alternative 2 Price (%) 0.08 0.86 1.17 Market Output (%) -0.08 -0.85 -1.16 Value of Domestic Shipments (%) ($MMa) 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Plant Closures 0 6 1 a1994$ Note: Results based on demand elasticity of -1.0 and supply elasticity of 50.0. APPENDIX C: SENSITIVITY ANALYSES: DEMAND AND SUPPLY ELASTICITIES C-4 ------- APPENDIX D SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS OF EMISSION CONTROL TECHNOLOGIES This appendix presents the results of sensitivity analyses that explore the degree to which predicted plant closures in the slabstock sector are sensitive to the assignment of control technologies. As has been previously discussed, there are several different technologies which can satisfy the requirements of the regulatory alternatives. When calculating nationwide regulatory costs, assumptions have been made as to the specific technology, or combination of technologies, that model plants would adopt (and thus the costs that would be incurred). Different assumptions about which control technology combinations plants will adopt affect the costs and impacts of the alternatives. Predicted closures for the slabstock segment are sensitive to control technology assignments. Tables A-15 and A-17 (see Appendix A), show that Acetone and Forced Cooling provide the same level of emission reductions at very different costs. General economic principle dictates that given the comparable performance of the control technologies, facilities would choose the lowest-cost option. However, because there are facilities in the industry using the higher-cost technology in favor of the lower-cost options, the EPA includes the higher-cost technology in the distribution of technologies to model plants. As Table D-1 indicates, switching compliance technologies chosen by model plants MP2 and MP3 (from forced cooling to acetone) will decrease predicted plant closures from two to one under the MACT Floor, from three to one under Regulatory Alternative 1, and from four to one under Regulatory Alternative 2. APPENDIX C: SENSITIVITY ANALYSES: DEMAND AND SUPPLY ELASTICITIES C-5 ------- Table D-1 PREDICTED PLANT CLOSURES WITH REASSIGNMENT OF SLABSTOCK ABA EMISSION REDUCTION TECHNOLOGIES Technology MACT Floor Cardi 0 Aceto ne VPF Force d Coolin g Chem Alts Reg Alt I Cardi 0 Aceto ne VPF Force d Coolin g Reg Alt II Cardi 0 + Chem Alts Aceto ne VPF Force d Coolin g+Ch em Alts Number of Facilities Using the Technology (Original) MP1 4 1 0 2 12 13 3 0 3 10 3 0 6 MP2 9 1 0 4 14 18 4 0 6 15 3 1 9 Number of Facilities Using the Technology (Revised) MP1 4 3 0 0 12 13 6 0 0 10 9 0 0 MP2 9 5 0 0 14 18 10 0 0 15 3 1 9 Predicted Closures Original 2 3 4 Revised 1 1 1 APPENDIX D: SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS OF EMISSION CONTROL TECHNOLOGIES D-2 ------- TECHNICAL REPORT DATA (Please read Instructions on reverse before completing) 1. REPORT NO. EPA-452/R-96-012 3. RECIPIENT'S ACCESSION NO. 4. TITLE AND SUBTITLE Economic Impact Analysis of the Proposed NESHAP for Flexible Polyurethane Foam 5. REPORT DATE September 1996 6. PERFORMING ORGANIZATION CODE 7. AUTHOR(S) U.S. EPA Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards Innovative Strategies and Economics Group 8. PERFORMING ORGANIZATION REPORT NO. 9. PERFORMING ORGANIZATION NAME AND ADDRESS U.S. Environmental Protection Agency Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards Air Quality Strategies and Standards Division (MD-15) Research Triangle Park, NC 27711 10. PROGRAM ELEMENT NO. 11. CONTRACT/GRANT NO. 12. SPONSORING AGENCY NAME AND ADDRESS John Seitz, Director Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards Office of Air and Radiation U.S. Environmental Protection Agency Research Triangle Park, NC 27711 13. TYPE OF REPORT AND PERIOD COVERED 14. SPONSORING AGENCY CODE EPA/200/04 15. SUPPLEMENTARY NOTES 16. ABSTRACT APPENDIX D: SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS OF EMISSION CONTROL TECHNOLOGIES D-3 ------- EPA Form 2220-1 (Rev. 4-77) The report evaluates the distribution of economic impacts among various members of society (producers and consumers) from the regulatory alternatives considered for the Flexible Polyurethane Foam NESHAP. 17.KEY WORDS AND DOCUMENT ANALYSIS a. DESCRIPTORS Economic Impact Analysis National Emission Standard for Hazardous Air Pollutants (NESHAP) Cost Impacts Regulatory Flexibility Analysis 18. DISTRIBUTION STATEMENT Release Unlimited b. IDENTIFIERS/OPEN ENDED TERMS Air Pollution control Economics 19. SECURITY CLASS (Report) Unclassified 20. SECURITY CLASS (Page) Unclassified c. COSATI Field/Group 21. NO. OF PAGES 22. PRICE PREVIOUS EDITION IS OBSOLETE ------- |