United States      EPA Science Advisory     EPA-SAB-EEAC-03-004
      Environmental      Board (1400A)          December 2002
      Protection Agency     Washington DC        iviviv.epa.gov/sab
&EPA AFFORDABILITY CRITERIA
      FOR SMALL DRINKING
      WATER SYSTEMS:  AN
      EPA SCIENCE ADVISORY
      BOARD REPORT
      A REPORT BY THE
      ENVIRONMENTAL ECONOMICS
      ADVISORY COMMITTEE OF THE
      EPA SCIENCE ADVISORY
      BOARD (SAB)

-------
                    UNITED STATES ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY
                                  WASHINGTON, D.C.  20460
                                   December 3 0,2002
                                                            OFFICE OF THE ADMINISTRATOR
                                                              SCIENCE ADVISORY BOARD
EPA-SAB-EEAC-03-004

Honorable Christine Todd Whitman
Administrator
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency
1200 Pennsylvania Avenue, NW
Washington, DC 20460

       Subject:      Affordability Criteria for Small Drinking Water Systems: An EPA Science
                    Advisory Board Report

Dear Governor Whitman:

       The Environmental Economics Advisory Committee (EEAC) of EPA's Science Advisory
Board (SAB) met on June 13, 2002, and again on August 12, 2002 to review a number of aspects
associated with the Agency's affordability criteria that is used to determine the availability of
small drinking water system variances under the Safe Drinking Water Act.

       The charge to the SAB's Environmental Economics Advisory Committee asked for
advice in four general areas.  1) EPA's basic approach to determining affordability for small
systems (i.e., comparing average compliance costs with an expenditure margin), 2) components
of the affordability  determination method (i.e., use of median household income, alternatives to
the 2.5% affordability threshold, calculation of the expenditure baseline), 3) the application,
focus and/or definition of affordability (i.e., the use of separate national level affordability
criteria for ground water vs. surface water systems; the need for making affordable technology
determinations on a regional rather than a national basis), and 4) whether financial assistance
should be considered in EPA's national level affordability criteria.

       In this letter, we highlight only a few of the EEAC's findings. First, the Committee
believes that EPA's basic approach to assessing the affordability of National Primary Drinking
Water Regulations (NPDWRs) for small systems is justified on the basis of equity and efficiency
considerations, as well as considerations of administrative practicality. At the same time, the
Agency should be aware of the limitations of this basic approach, and modify it where
appropriate and possible.

       In particular, the Agency should consider options of system consolidation, and take these
into account when analyzing the nature and duration of any relaxation of drinking water quality
requirements.  In addition, the Agency should recognize that in light of significant existing
heterogeneity among small systems, the use of a national trigger as a screening device suggests

-------
the adoption of a fairly low affordability threshold. Partly because of this, the Committee
encourages EPA to develop clear and formal guidelines about when variances should be granted
at the local level, and the Committee encourages EPA to conduct research — to be shared with
community water suppliers — into possible mechanisms for achieving greater equity in
distribution of water costs to individuals.

       If the basic approach is maintained, the Agency should consider lower measures than
median income that better capture impacts on disadvantaged households, recognizing that the
effect of such a lower percentile, either within water districts or across water districts, would be
to make it easier to trigger the affordability threshold. The Agency should also consider lower
percentages than the current 2.5% as the income percentage for the national level affordability
threshold. We say this because the national affordability threshold has never been exceeded, but
some small water systems appear to have genuinely struggled with costs, suggesting that the
2.5% rule is too high. However, a change should be made only in conjunction with the
development of clear and formal guidelines about when variances should be provided at the local
level.

       We appreciate the opportunity to review and provide advice on the Agency's small
system affordability criteria.  The EPA Science Advisory Board would be pleased to further
discuss any of the recommendations described in this report, and we look forward to your
response.

                                       Sincerely,


       /Signed/                                  /Signed/

Dr. William Glaze, Chair                  Dr. Robert N. Stavins, Chair
EPA Science Advisory Board             Environmental Economics Advisory Committee
                                        EPA Science Advisory Board

-------
                                      NOTICE
       This report has been written as part of the activities of the EPA Science Advisory Board,
a public advisory group providing extramural scientific information and advice to the
Administrator and other officials of the Environmental Protection Agency. The Board is
structured to provide balanced, expert assessment of scientific matters related to problems facing
the Agency. This report has not been reviewed for approval by the Agency and, hence, the
contents of this report do not necessarily represent the views and policies of the Environmental
Protection Agency, nor of other agencies in the Executive Branch of the Federal government, nor
does mention of trade names of commercial products constitute a recommendation for use.
Distribution and Availability: This EPA Science Advisory Board report is provided to the EPA
Administrator, senior Agency management, appropriate program staff, interested members of the
public, and is posted on the SAB website (www.epa.gov/sab). Information on its availability is
also provided in the SAB's monthly newsletter (Happenings at the Science Advisory Board).
Additional copies and further information are available from the SAB Staff [U.S. EPA Science
Advisory Board (1400A), 1200 Pennsylvania Avenue, NW, Washington, DC 20460-0001; 202-
564-4533].

-------
                                     ABSTRACT
       This report represents the conclusions and recommendations of the U.S. Environmental
Protection Agency's Science Advisory Board regarding the EPA affordability criteria which
determines whether variances shall be available to small systems as they implement maximum
contaminant level regulations under the Safe Drinking Water Act.  The Agency asked the SAB
for advice on:  1) EPA's basic approach to determining affordability for small systems (i.e.,
comparing average compliance costs with an expenditure margin), 2) components of the
affordability determination method (i.e., use of median household income, alternatives to the
2.5% affordability threshold, calculation of the expenditure baseline), 3) the application, focus
and/or definition of affordability (i.e., the use of separate national level affordability criteria for
ground water vs. surface water systems; the need for making affordable  technology
determinations on a regional rather than a national basis), and 4) whether financial assistance
should be considered in EPA's national level affordability criteria.

       The report presents the SAB's findings and recommendations on the Agency's charge
questions.  The report notes that Agency's basic approach is justified on the basis of equity and
efficiency considerations, as well as considerations of administrative practicality. The SAB also
addressed limitations of the basic approach and suggested EPA modify it where appropriate and
possible. They encouraged the Agency to consider options of system consolidation when
analyzing the nature and duration of any standards relaxation and noted  that the use of a national
trigger as a screening device suggests the adoption of a fairly low affordability threshold. The
SAB encouraged EPA to develop clear and formal guidelines about when variances should be
granted at the local level, and to conduct research into possible mechanisms for achieving greater
equity  in distribution of water costs to individuals. The report carries additional
recommendations.

KEY WORDS: Affordability; Affordability Criteria; Variances; Small Systems; Community
Water  Systems; Compliance Technologies; MCLs; Safe Drinking Water Act
                                           11

-------
                    U.S. Environmental Protection Agency
                         EPA Science Advisory Board
               Environmental Economics Advisory Committee*


CHAIR
Dr. Robert Stavins, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA

SAB MEMBERS
Dr. Dallas Burtraw, Resources for the Future, Washington, DC

Dr. Lawrence Goulder, Stanford University, Stanford, CA

Dr. W. Michael Hanemann, University of California, Berkeley, CA

Dr. Gloria Helfand, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI

Dr. Catherine Kling, Iowa State University, Ames, IA

Dr. Richard Norgaard, University of California-Berkeley, Berkeley, CA

Dr. Stephen Polasky, University of Minnesota, St. Paul, MN

Dr. Hilary Sigman, Rutgers University, New Brunswick, NJ

SCIENCE ADVISORY BOARD STAFF
Mr. Thomas Miller, Designated Federal Officer, 1200 Pennsylvania Avenue, NW, Washington,
      DC

Ms. Diana Pozun, Management Analyst, 1200 Pennsylvania Ave., NW, Washington, DC

Mr. E. Catesby Beck, Intern, 1200 Pennsylvania Ave., NW, Washington, DC

*Members of this SAB Panel consist of
      a)     SAB Members: Experts appointed by the Administrator to serve on one of the
             SAB Standing Committees
                                        in

-------
                             TABLE OF CONTENTS
1 BACKGROUND 	1
       1.1 Statutory Context and the Affordability Concept	1
       1.2 The Charge  	2
       1.3 Review Documents  	3

2 CONSIDERATIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS  	4
       2.1 General Conclusions 	4
       2.2 Responses to Specific Charge Questions	4
             2.2.1 Charge Question 1  	4
                   2.2.1.1 Overview	4
                   2.2.1.2 Efficiency and Equity Issues	4
                   2.2.1.3 The Alternative of Financial Compensation  	8
                   2.2.1.4 The Usefulness of a National "Trigger"  	9
                   2.2.1.5 Summary  	9
             2.2.2 Charge Question 2  	10
                   2.2.2.1 Measures Other than Median	10
                   2.2.2.2 Alternative Measures	11
                   2.2.2.3 Effects of Alternatives	11
             2.2.3 Charge Question 3  	11
             2.2.4 Charge Question 4  	12
             2.2.5 Charge Question 5  	13
             2.2.6 Charge Question 6  	13
             2.2.7 Charge Question 7  	14
                   2.2.7.1 Regional vs. National Determinations	14
                   2.2.7.2 Available Information 	14

REFERENCES 	R-l
                                         IV

-------
                                1. BACKGROUND
1.1 Statutory Context and the Affordability Concept

       When EPA establishes a National Primary Drinking Water Regulation (NPDWR) it must
consider the impact of regulatory compliance on small community water systems (those with a
service population of 10,000 or fewer).  Major provisions for dealing with this issue are linked to
the concept of "affordability."  EPA must identify affordable "Small System Compliance
Technologies" for each rule, and if affordable compliance technologies are not available, EPA
must identify "Small System Variance Technologies" in lieu of compliance technologies. Even
though the variance technologies may not achieve compliance with the Maximum Contaminant
Level (MCL) - the standard — or Treatment Technique in the rule, the variance technology still
must achieve the maximum reduction/inactivation that is affordable while considering system
size and source water quality. Further, the variance technology must be "protective of public
health." In addition, States are authorized to grant "Small System Variances"  from the
MCL/Treatment Technique for the life of the variance technology.

       Affordability is a concept provided for in the Safe Drinking Water Act to assist in making
decisions on the need for variance technologies and variances. EPA developed the National
Level Affordability Criterion to be used in making the decision on whether affordable
compliance technologies exist for small systems. EPA determines affordability of a rule through
the following relationship:

       EM = AT -B

where:

       EM (Expenditure Margin) is the maximum increase that can be imposed by treatment
       and still be considered affordable),

       AT (Affordability Threshold) is the upper limit for the cost of water bills including
       costs for treatment, distribution, and operation (the current Affordability threshold is
       2.5% of Median Household Income — MHI), and

       B (Baseline component) is from current annual water bills and median household
       income.

If the projected compliance cost for the rule is less than the available expenditure margin then
the technology is affordable.

       The National Level Affordability Criteria determination was published in August 1998.
EPA identified the Affordability Threshold of 2.5% MHI.  Data sources used by EPA to develop
the baseline component included the Community Water System Survey (CWSS) and the US
Census. MHI was selected as the metric because EPA preferred using an average metric instead
of a worst case.  The threshold was tied to costs associated with other risk reduction activities
that could be carried out at the household level. EPA contemplates updating the baseline data
and the methodology.

       EPA consulted with the  Science Advisory Board's Drinking Water Committee (DWC) on
the development of their affordability criterion during a June, 1998 meeting.  The DWC decided


                                           1

-------
to prepare an Advisory as a result of that interaction (EPA SAB, 1999). Among other things,
that Advisory stated that the documentation on the affordability criteria would benefit from
"...additional input by economists and policy analysts."

1.2 The Charge

       In the final charge (dated March 26, 2002) EPA asked the SAB to consider the economic
issues associated with the methodology for developing their national-level affordability criteria,
as well as the factors that were used to establish the criteria. Specifically, EPA asked that while,
"Taking into consideration the structure of the Safe Drinking Water Act and the limitations of
readily available data and information sources, what is the [SAB's] opinion of the Agency
national level affordability criterion, [the] methodology for deriving the criterion, and [the]
approach to applying that criterion to national primary drinking water regulations?  As part of
the committee's review EPA asked the SAB to respond to the following questions:

       a)      What is the SAB's view of the Agency's basic approach of comparing average
              compliance costs for an NPDWR with  an expenditure margin, which is derived as
              the difference between an affordability threshold and an expenditure baseline?

       b)     If the basic approach is retained, should a measure other than median income that
              captures the impact on more disadvantaged households be used as the basis for
              the affordability threshold? If so, what alternative measures (for example 10th or
              25th income percentile, poverty level income) should the Agency consider and
              why?  What would be the likely effect  of such alternatives on existing and future
              national level affordable technology determinations?

       c)      What alternatives should the Agency consider to 2.5% as the income percentage
              for the national level affordability threshold and what would be the likely effect
              of such alternatives on existing and future national level affordable technology
              determinations? What basis should the Agency use to select from among such
              alternatives? Should the Agency  use costs of other household goods and services
              or  risk reduction activities as a basis for setting the affordability threshold as was
              done in the development of the current criteria?

       d)     Does the Committee believe the Agency should consider other approaches to
              calculating the national "expenditure baseline" than those used by the Agency
              heretofore?

       e)      Does the Committee believe that separate national level affordability criteria
              should be developed for ground water and surface water systems?

       f)      Should the Agency include an evaluation of the potential availability of financial
              assistance (for example Drinking  Water State Revolving Fund) in its national
              level affordability criteria?  If so,  how could the potential availability of such
              financial assistance that reduces household burden be taken into consideration?

       g)     Is there a need for making affordable technology determinations on a regional
              rather than a national basis?  Does adequate readily available information exist to
              support  such an approach? EPA is still exploring the degree of flexibility
              afforded by SDWA to make regional determinations, but would appreciate the
              Committee's advice on whether such determinations are feasible and warranted.

-------
1.3 Review Documents

      EPA provided the SAB with the following documents that explain issues associated with
the affordability criteria under the Safe Drinking Water Act.

      a)     Report to Congress (March 2002)
      b)     Final Arsenic in Drinking Water Rule (small systems excerpt)(January 2001)
      c)     Small System Compliance Technology List for the Surface Water Treatment Rule
             and Total Coliform Rule (EPA 815-R-98-001)
      d)     Small System Compliance Technology List for the Non-Microbial Contaminants
             Regulated Before 1996 (EPA 815-R-98-002)
      e)     Variance Technology Findings for Contaminants Regulated Before 1996 (EPA
             815-R-98-003)

-------
             2. CONSIDERATIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS
2.1 General Conclusions

       EPA's basic approach to assessing the "affordability" of National Primary Drinking
Water Regulations (NPDWRs) for small systems is intended to address the reality that small
systems frequently face higher costs of meeting given standards. If the anticipated cost of
compliance would put small systems (on average, on a national basis) above an "affordability
threshold," then such systems  are allowed to apply for variances. The Committee finds that this
basic approach is justified on the basis of equity and efficiency considerations, as well as
considerations of administrative practicality.

       Although EPA's basic  approach has merit, the Agency should be aware of its limitations,
and modify it where appropriate and possible.  In particular, the Agency should consider options
of system consolidation, and take these into account when analyzing the nature and duration of
any relaxation of drinking water quality requirements.  In addition, the Agency should recognize
that in light of heterogeneity among small systems, the use of a national trigger as a screening
device  suggests the adoption of a  fairly low affordability threshold. The Committee strongly
encourages EPA to develop clear  and formal guidelines about when variances should be granted
at the local level, and the Committee encourages EPA to conduct research — to be shared with
community water suppliers — into possible mechanisms for achieving greater equity in
distribution of water costs to individuals.

       If the basic approach is maintained, the Agency should consider measures other than
median income that better capture impacts on disadvantaged households. Within-district income
inequalities (to the extent that the poor are not protected from cost increases) and between-
district income inequalities argue  for the use of lower income percentiles than median income.
The effect of such a lower percentile, either within water districts or across water districts, would
be to make it easier to trigger the  affordability threshold.

       The Agency should also consider lower percentages than the current 2.5% as the income
percentage for the national level affordability threshold.  The national affordability threshold has
never been exceeded, but some small water systems appear to have genuinely struggled with
costs, suggesting that the 2.5% rule is too high. EPA should consider a lower percentage than
2.5, but a change should be made  only in conjunction with the development of clear and formal
guidelines about when variances should be provided at the local level.

       Should the Agency consider other approaches to calculating the national "expenditure
baseline?" The Committee finds that there is no better approach to calculating the national
expenditure baseline, but it wishes to remind EPA that the national-level determination of
affordability can serve only a screening function. Again, the  Committee encourages the Agency
to develop guidelines for the case-by-case assessment of affordability in individual water supply
systems that seek a variance.

       Finally, the Committee recommends that EPA make its affordable technology
determinations on a regional — or even local — basis, rather than a national basis. Regional
income measures and expenditure baselines would capture affordability relative to the resources
available in a community more accurately than the current national values.  On the other hand,
continued reliance on a national affordability threshold is necessary to implement a fairness goal.

-------
2.2 Responses to specific Charge questions.

       2.2.1 Charge Question 1. What is the SAB's view of the Agency's basic approach of
              comparing average compliance costs for an NPDWR with an expenditure margin,
              which is derived as the difference between an affordability threshold and an
              expenditure baseline?

              2.2.1.1  Overview

       This question asks for the Environmental Economics Advisory Committee's (hereafter,
the Committee's) view of EPA's basic approach to assessing the "affordability" of National
Primary Drinking Water Regulations  (NPDWRs) for small systems. EPA's basic approach is
intended to address the reality that small systems frequently face higher costs of meeting the
given standards. The basic approach  is to allow small systems to apply for variances if the
anticipated cost of compliance would put such systems (on average, on a national basis) above
an "affordability threshold."

       The Committee finds that the basic approach is justified  on the basis of equity and
efficiency considerations, as well as considerations of administrative practicality.  At the same
time, the EEAC recommends that the Agency consider some modifications of the basic approach
to address important long-run efficiency issues and to deal more effectively with heterogeneity
among small systems.  These findings stem from attention to the following questions:  (a) Is
special treatment for small systems justified on the basis of equity and efficiency? (b) Is the
special treatment afforded small systems under the basic approach superior to the alternative  of
Federal financial compensation to small systems? (c) Is it reasonable to  employ a national
"trigger" to allow for special treatment? Below we address  each of these questions in turn.

              2.2.1.2  Efficiency and Equity Issues

       The Committee finds that efficiency considerations support the basic approach. We find
that considerations of equity also support the basic approach, although — as discussed below —
competing equity concerns would tend to favor an alternative approach.

              a)  Significance of Differences in Cost, Income, and Benefits

       The equity and efficiency issues are closely linked with differences between small and
large systems in the costs and benefits of improvements in drinking water quality, as well as
differences in average  incomes.  To clarify the issues, it is useful to begin with  the simplest case,
where the systems differ only in terms of cost of changes in drinking water quality, and then to
move to more complex cases involving other differences as  well. In all cases, it is assumed that
the Federal standard enforces a level of water quality that for large  systems is reasonably
efficient  (marginal costs are less than or equal to marginal benefits1).
'Marginal costs refer to the increment to total cost associated with a unit increase in drinking water quality improvement, and
marginal benefits refer to the increment to total benefits associated with a unit increase in drinking water quality improvement. We
display the marginal benefit curves as downward sloping to allow for the possibility that the marginal benefits or willingness to pay
for drinking water quality declines with improvements in drinking water quality.  The qualitative conclusions from this subsection
are unchanged in the limiting case where the marginal benefit curves are flat (that is, where the willingness to pay for water quality
is constant within the range of water quality under consideration).

-------
       Case 1:  All systems (large and small) have identical marginal benefit schedules for
       improvements in drinking water quality, and identical average incomes of water
       customers. But small systems have higher marginal costs of achieving improvements in
       drinking water quality.

       The situation is depicted in the figure below. Under these circumstances, it is inefficient
for small systems to meet the same standard (Q,) as the larger systems. Relaxing the drinking
water quality requirement for small systems improves efficiency. Requiring small systems to
meet the standard Qx may also be inequitable since small systems must pay greater unit costs
than
                                MC
                                                                             MC
    Qo
    (Status
     Quo)
  Qi
 (Federal
Requirement)
Qo
(Status
 Quo)
   Qi
 (Federal
Requirement)
              Small Systems
                                  Large Systems
                                     Case 1
large systems but receive the same benefits per unit.  Thus relaxing the requirement for small
systems may also improve equity.

       Case 2:  Customers of small systems are assumed to have lower than average incomes
       than customers of larger systems.  Otherwise same as Case 1.

       By assumption, this case does not alter the marginal cost and marginal benefit curves
relative to Case 1. Thus the efficiency argument is unchanged. But, relative to Case 1, the
equity argument for modifying the requirement is strengthened in this case, since meeting the
regulations would involve a greater relative income sacrifice for customers of small water
systems.

-------
       Case 3: Marginal benefits of water quality are smaller, in general, for customers of
       small systems than customers of large systems. Otherwise same as Case 2.

       In this case, the marginal benefit schedule, as well as the marginal cost schedule, is lower
for small systems. The lower marginal benefit schedule could reflect the fact that customers of
small systems have lower incomes and hence lower willingness to pay for water quality
increases. The situation is depicted below.

       This circumstance intensifies both the efficiency argument and the equity argument,
relative to case 1. The lower Marginal Benefit schedule for the small systems intensifies the
efficiency argument because now, for customers of small systems, the net benefits of meeting the
Federal standard (Q,) would be lower than in cases 1 and 2.
                               MC
    Qo
    (Status
    Quo)
 Qi
 (Federal
Requirement)
                                  MB

                                 Water Quality
                                                                             MC
Qo
(Status
 Quo)
  Qi
 (Federal
Requirement)
             Small Systems
                                 Large Systems
                                     Case  3
       Thus, under certain circumstances, both efficiency and equity considerations favor easing
the requirements for small systems. To the extent that small systems have higher marginal costs,
there is both an equity and efficiency basis for modifying the requirements for small systems.  To
the extent that average incomes are lower for customers of small systems, the equity argument is
strengthened.  To the extent that MB rises with income, the equity and efficiency arguments are
strengthened further.

              b) Safe Drinking Water as a Right

       One might adopt the view that safe drinking water is a right that all citizens should enjoy.
Whether or not safe drinking water is a right is fundamentally a question of equity. To the extent
that this view is correct, the economic analysis changes.  If safe drinking water is a right, then

-------
property rights have changed and this right is now an asset owned by everyone, including people
in small water systems in poor communities.

       The change in property rights affects the efficiency calculation. In the previous analysis,
where no basic right to clean water was assumed, efficiency calculations depended on
individuals' willingness to pay for improved drinking water quality. In contrast, if it is assumed
that people have a basic right to drinking water quality, then the efficiency calculations need
refer to individuals' willingness to accept reduced drinking water quality - that is, the amount
required to compensate them for each marginal reduction in that quality.

       Under these circumstances the calculation of efficient levels of drinking water quality, in
small and large systems, would be based on diagrams somewhat different from those used above.
The diagrams would involve schedules for marginal required  compensation (or willingness to
accept) and marginal cost-savings, as functions of the reduction in drinking water quality.
Efficiency is  maximized where the marginal cost-saving from reduced use of resources for
drinking water treatment equals the marginal required compensation (or willingness to accept)
for reduced drinking water quality. In general, the marginal willingness to accept schedule lies
above the marginal willingness to pay schedule considered earlier: hence the shift in the
definition of rights implies that,  other things equal, the efficient level of drinking water quality is
higher.

       The question of rights is related to the evaluation of Federal  assistance as an alternative
to the basic approach. We indicate its relevance in subsection 2.2.1.3 below.

              c) Long-Run Efficiency Considerations

       The basic approach could produce negative efficiency consequences over the longer
term,  because it could retard the movement toward efficient consolidation. The incentives to
consolidate small, inefficient systems are weakened when such systems are granted variances
from the Federal standards. The Committee recommends that the EPA review, on a case by case
basis, the options for consolidation of small systems. In circumstances where consolidation is a
viable long-run alternative for small systems, the EPA should take this into account in  deciding
the nature and duration of any relaxation of the drinking water quality requirements for these
systems.

              2.2.1.3 The Alternative of Financial Compensation

       An alternative to the basic approach adopted by EPA would  be Federal financial
assistance to  small communities to subsidize the cost of meeting drinking water quality
standards, and thereby reduce costs to residents in areas using small systems.2 We consider the
attractiveness of this alternative in terms of equity, efficiency, and administrative practicality.

       The alternative of Financial Assistance may find support from the viewpoint that safe
drinking water is a basic right that all citizens should enjoy, and that the Federal government
may have the responsibility to protect that right (or compensate individuals who lose this right).
Under this viewpoint, the Federal government would be obligated either to provide financial
assistance to enable localities to pay for water treatment that leads to safe drinking water, or
alternatively to compensate localities to the  extent that their right is  not protected and they do not
have high drinking water quality.
2This would be in addition to whatever financial assistance is already available.

-------
       The arguments for or against this viewpoint are mainly equity arguments.  We cannot
settle these equity issues here.  However, we note that the loss of drinking water quality in small
systems is sometimes due to activities by individuals or industry in the same localities. When
the responsible parties are local, the argument that the Federal government (as opposed to other
parties) has an obligation to compensate individuals or provide assistance seems weaker.
Indeed, some would claim that Federal assistance is warranted only when there is no obvious
other party that is responsible for degrading drinking water quality. In addition, we note that this
alternative poses significant practical difficulties. Instituting such assistance would require a
change in the statute, which would require an act of Congress.  Such considerations seem to
render this alternative less attractive than the basic approach.

              2.2.1.4 The Usefulness of a National "Trigger"

       Under the Agency's basic approach, small systems become eligible for consideration for
variances if the costs for systems, on a nationwide basis, exceed an affordability threshold.3  If
small systems collectively meet this condition, then a "trigger" is pulled in the sense that
individual small systems can apply for a modification to the requirements.  Given the
considerable heterogeneity among small systems in terms of their costs and benefits, as well as
the incomes of local customers, the use of a national trigger based on national averages is
problematic.  Ideally, it would be better to allow all water supply systems to apply for special
relief from the Federal requirements, and consider every applicant on a case-by-case basis.  But
it may be necessary to employ this initial eligibility approach in order to reduce administrative
costs.

       The use of this national "trigger" justifies setting the affordability threshold based on
considerations of heterogeneity. When a national trigger is employed, the risk exists that small
systems as a whole will  not face costs that entitle them to apply for modified rules, even though
particular small systems face costs well in excess of the affordability threshold. In this case,
certain small  systems would not be able to apply for modifications to the regulations, even
though their costs are well above the threshold. For this reason, the affordability threshold
should be relatively easy to reach, to avoid the possibility of penalizing particularly  costly small
systems.  A balance needs to be struck between the desire to screen applicants and the desire to
avoid excluding particularly high-cost systems.

              2.2.1.5 Summary

       In sum, the Committee finds that the basic approach has merit. Efficiency and equity
considerations tend to support this approach. Moreover, this approach seems superior to the
alternative of providing  financial compensation to small systems.

       The Agency should be aware of limitations to the basic approach, however, and modify it
where  possible. In particular, the Agency should consider options of system consolidation, and
take this  into account when considering the nature and duration of any relaxation of drinking
water quality requirements. In addition, the Agency should recognize that in light of the
heterogeneity among small systems the use of a national trigger as a screening device suggests
the adoption of a fairly low affordability threshold.
3Note that the application of variance technologies may still cause significant cost increases for some systems, partly because some
systems may have no treatment ex ante.

-------
       The Committee encourages EPA to develop clear and formal guidelines about when
variances should be granted at the local level. In addition, the Committee encourages EPA to
conduct research — to be shared with community water suppliers — into possible mechanisms
for achieving greater equity in distribution of water costs to individuals.  In particular, EPA
could provide suggestions to local authorities for alternative pricing mechanisms, such as lifeline
rates,4 as instruments for easing the financial burden on low income households.

       2.2.2  Charge Question 2. If the basic approach is retained, should a measure other than
              median income that captures the impact on more disadvantaged households be
              used as the basis for the affordability threshold?  If so, what alternative measures
              (for example 10th or 25th income percentile,  poverty level income) should the
              Agency consider and why?  What would be the likely effect of such alternatives
              on existing and future national level affordable technology determinations?

              2.2.2.1. Measures other than Median. If the basic approach is retained,
              should a measure other than median income that captures the impact on
              more disadvantaged households be used as the basis for  the  affordability
              threshold?

       There are grounds for consideration  of measures other than median income.  The first
concern about using median income arises from income inequality within water districts.  Water
bills are paid at the household level.  Even if the median household can afford to pay the
increased water bill, poorer households within a water district may find it unaffordable. This
argues for considering the use of a lower percentile than the median.  On the other hand, using a
lower threshold might reduce drinking water quality for more affluent members of a community
who may want cleaner water enough to be willing to pay fully for the attendant costs.
Alternative funding mechanisms —  such as lifeline rates — could be an effective means of
distributing costs to non-low-income households. In this case, the aggregate affordability for the
water district is the issue, which would argue for median (or even mean) household income.

       A second concern about using median income as the basis for the affordability threshold
arises from income inequality across water districts within a size class. EPA makes a national
level determination for all water districts within a size class. As long as the median household
income for all water districts in a given size class is high enough, then no water district within
that  size  class may be considered for a variance.  This result holds even though the increase in
water bills may far exceed 2.5% of median household income for some water districts within the
size  class. Income inequality across water districts within  a size class is particularly
troublesome, because there is no easy way to protect poor districts, as there is with poor
households within a water district through redistributing costs among households.5
4Lifeline rates refer to block pricing structures, sometimes employed with electricity, whereby the first block—intended to represent
what may be considered to be "essential uses" of electricity — is priced very modestly in an effort to protect low-income households.

5An alternative to median income is mean income. Support for median income comes from concern that a few wealthy households
could skew mean income. In addition, it is the median voter that is pivotal in a voting context. Support for mean income comes from
the fact that it is tied to generally accepted welfare measures: mean willingness-to-pay and mean willingness-to-accept. Further, mean
income is an indication of the total income in a water district, and may be a superior measure of how able a district is to subsidize
its lowest income households.


                                             10

-------
              2.2.2.2 Alternative Measures. If so, what alternative measures (for example,
              10th or 25th income, poverty level income) should the Agency consider and
              why?

       Within-district income inequalities (to the extent that the poor are not protected from cost
increases) and between-district income inequalities raise arguments for consideration of lower
income percentiles than median income.  There are several approaches that could be taken. One
option is to keep the current formula but specify a lower income percentile within water districts
(for example, 10th or 25th percentile). This approach would increase the likelihood that an
affordable compliance technology would not be found, and the entire class of communities in a
category would be eligible to apply for variances.

       A second option, designed to address the between-di strict income inequality issue, is to
consider whether a certain percentage of districts (for example, 10% or 25%) fall below the
threshold. This threshold could be set using median income or some lower income percentile as
in the first option.  If that percentage of communities falls below the threshold, then those
communities that could show that they fall below the threshold would be eligible to apply for
variances.

       A third option would be to base the threshold on some measure of dispersion, such as
variance or standard deviation, in addition to the median.  For example, instead of median
income level, an alternative would be to take the income level at 1, 1.5, or 2  standard deviations
below the mean. If the baseline component is set in the same manner, then this approach would
act similarly to the first option.

       The Committee believes that dealing with between-di strict income inequalities is
important, perhaps through something like option 2 or 3. While there is consensus  on the
Committee that income inequality argues for looking at income levels below the median, how far
below the median is less clear.  Perhaps the 25th percentile or 1.5 standard deviations below the
mean is reasonable, but this is a value judgment for which we can offer no hard and fast
guidance.

              2.2.2.3 Effects of Alternatives. What would be the likely effect of such
              alternatives  on existing and future national level affordable technology
              determinations?

       The effect of a lower percentile, either within water districts or across water districts,
would be to make it easier to reach the affordability threshold.

       2.2.3 Charge Question 3. What alternatives should the Agency consider to 2.5% as the
              income percentage for the national level affordability threshold, and what would
              be the likely effect of such alternatives on existing and future national level
              affordable technology determinations? What basis should the Agency use to
              select  from among such alternatives? Should the Agency use costs of other
              household goods and  services or risk reduction activities as a basis for setting the
              affordability threshold as was done in the development of the current criteria?

       While the answer to this question ultimately requires a judgment about fairness and
equity, EPA might consider looking to public policy decision rules in the health sciences and/or
transportation safety to determine whether their criteria are consistent with other policy decision-
criteria. Given that the main benefit of a drinking water quality system is to reduce morbidity


                                           11

-------
and/or premature mortality, a comparison with health sciences and/or transportation safety seems
appropriate. For example, in health economics, rules of thumb regarding whether a treatment is
cost-effective are apparently routinely applied to assess treatment options (Garber and
Phelps,19976).  The cost-effectiveness threshold used in the health sciences could be compared
with the cost effectiveness of spending 2.5% of the median income on drinking water system
technology to see if comparable affordability criteria are being used. Similar comparisons might
prove valuable from transportation safety policy and/or nutrition studies.

       While such comparisons may be useful, they are unlikely to provide conclusive guidance.
Thus, in addition to these comparisons, EPA might consider the fact that the national
affordability threshold has never been exceeded; hence the "trigger" necessary for variances to
be considered has never been activated. This fact, in conjunction with the evidence presented to
the Committee suggesting that some small water systems have genuinely struggled with costs,
suggests to us that the 2.5% rule is too high.  This, in turn, suggests that a lower cutoff should be
used, resulting in more likely triggering of the variance rule.

       In this case,  one would hope that superior state or local data and judgment will be used to
allow variances on a case-by-case basis, resulting in the provision of a variance only when a
clear and compelling case is established.  The committee is concerned that local agencies may be
under pressure to grant variances in many cases, whether the local situation calls for it or not.
So, while it is desirable to allow low-income, small water districts faced with very expensive
(per  capita) system upgrade requirements to be granted variances when such upgrades would
create real financial hardship, it is important that variances not be granted when the hardship is
not severe. To help assure that this balance is preserved, we suggest that EPA consider a lower
percentage than 2.5, but that this change be adopted only in conjunction with the development of
clear and formal guidelines about when variances should be provided at the local level. The
process of developing such guidelines and their implementation is not likely to be simple or
without costs, but we believe it is imperative if the threshold value is to be changed.

       2.2.4 Charge Question 4.  Does the Committee believe the Agency should consider
              other approaches to calculating the national  "expenditure baseline" than those
              used by the Agency heretofore?

       A national-level determination tends to neglect the variation in costs or other economic
circumstances that would be found if one looked individually at the different water utilities
within a given size category.  In effect, a national-level determination focuses attention on the
central tendency of the cost distribution, and neglects its dispersion. Many of the equity issues
that underlie the concept of affordability, however, are associated with the variation in costs.

       Given the variation in costs, we believe it is important that the national-level
determination of affordability serve only a screening function. The Committee encourages the
Agency to develop guidelines for the case-by-case assessment of affordability  in individual
water supply systems that seek a variance. That said, our answer to the question  is:  there is no
better approach to calculating the national expenditure baseline that we could recommend.

       The Committee has concerns about the use of any expenditure baseline. Including an
expenditure baseline in the formula implies that only the cumulative effect of drinking water
regulations matters to the determination of affordability.  This is inconsistent with making
variances available for regulations that impose especially high costs on small systems. It has the
^Further work on this subject is by Pedram and Briggs (2001) who develop an affordability curve for a range of program budgets.

                                            12

-------
undesirable effect that early regulations are likely to be considered affordable, whereas later,
after the affordability threshold has been exceeded, even regulations with trivial costs to small
systems will not. An alternative would eliminate the expenditure baseline from the formula and
evaluate the affordability of each set of regulations incrementally.  Using such an incremental
approach, however, would require a lower affordability threshold to offer sufficient protection to
users of small systems.

       2.2.5  Charge Question 5.  Does the Committee believe that separate national level
              affordability criteria should be developed for ground water and surface water
              systems?

       The argument for a separate affordability criterion for water systems utilizing ground
water stems from the fact that a significant number of (typically) small rural communities have
historically been able to draw upon groundwater as their source of supply with little or no
treatment. The facilities of these water systems may consist of little more than a pump, elevated
storage tank,  and simple chlorination system to prevent contamination in the distribution system.
Such a system may employ only a part-time, relatively narrowly skilled operator, and have a
footprint no larger than the base of the tower of the tank. It is argued that for these communities
to comply with drinking water quality regulations would entail incurring fixed costs of
establishing a "whole treatment system" rather than simply adding on to an existing system.

       In our judgment, the affordability criterion should be  the same for groundwater and
surface water systems.  While it may be true that many groundwater sources require little
treatment, some surface water supplies also require little treatment. There is great variation  in
treatment costs for both surface water and groundwater-based systems. Furthermore, historic
expenditures are not relevant, for historically nearly all systems had minimal treatment. Cost
and the ability of the community to pay are the issue, not the source of supply.

       2.2.6  Charge Question 6.  Should the Agency include an evaluation of the potential
              availability of financial assistance (for example Drinking Water State Revolving
              Fund) in its national level affordability criteria? If so, how could the potential
              availability of such financial assistance that reduces household burden be taken
              into consideration?

       Funding is  available to assist small systems through the Drinking Water State Revolving
Fund and the Rural Utilities Service of the U.S. Department of Agriculture.  These programs
employ affordability as one, but not the exclusive criterion for awarding assistance. Whether
these funds are adequate to assist all small systems that have difficulty meeting drinking water
standards is unclear. There is also uncertainty regarding the ability of small systems to apply for
these funds. Testimony from the National Rural Water Association indicates that "many small
systems fail to take advantage of the opportunity because they are unaware and often not capable
of doing the administrative work to secure the grant or loan."

       If this funding is readily available to many  or most systems facing affordability problems,
it seems appropriate to take the availability of this  funding into account in determining national
level affordability. Under this scenario, the ability of systems to afford treatment is clearly
affected by the  availability of this funding, and the affordability assessment should take these
sources into consideration. On the other hand, if funding is not commonly available to many
systems, then the fact that it is  available to some should  not affect the determination.  Systems
should have the affordability determination made using the factors that influence them; if
external funding sources are not likely to help them meet a new requirement, the affordability


                                           13

-------
determination should not take into account funding that will not reach most communities. EPA
should strive to provide information to small systems to help them realize what options are
available to them. This recommendation is not limited to small system affordability issues,
rather, it should be applied more broadly to all drinking water issues.

       2.2.7 Charge Question 7. Is there a need for making affordable technology
              determinations on a regional rather than a national basis?  Does adequate readily
              available information exist to  support such an approach? EPA is still exploring
              the degree of flexibility afforded by SDWA to make regional determinations, but
              would appreciate the Committee's advice on whether such determinations are
              feasible and warranted.

              2.2.7.1 Regional vs National Determinations. Is there a need for making
              affordable technology determinations on a regional rather than a national
              basis?

       The committee supports making  determinations on a regional or even a local basis. It
also supports adding an urban/rural distinction. Regional income measures and expenditure
baselines would capture affordability relative to the resources available in a community more
accurately than the current national values. However, a national  affordability threshold is
necessary to implement the fairness goal.

              2.2.7.2 Available Information. Does adequate readily available information
              exist to support such an approach?

       Income data are readily available for a more disaggregated analysis, but EPA derives the
expenditure baseline from a survey whose sample may be too small for reliable regional values.
Even if an expenditure baseline continues to be part of the formula and data do not support
regional variation in this value, using regional income measures would still improve the current
formula.
                                           14

-------
                                 REFERENCES

EPA Science Advisory Board (SAB). 1999. An SAB Advisory on the National-Level
      Affordability Criteria and Technologies for Small Systems Under the 1996 Amendments
      to the Safe Drinking Water Act. EPA-SAB-DWC-ADV-99-001, US EPA Science
      Advisory Board, Washington, DC, December, 1999.

Garber, A. and Phelps, C. 1997. Economic Foundations of Cost-Effectiveness Analysis,
      J. of Health Economics Jj5: 1-31.

Pedram, S. and A. Briggs. 2001. Affordability and Cost-Effectiveness: Decision-Making on the
      Cost-Effectiveness Plane, Health Economics 10: 675-680.
                                        R-l

-------