EPA 742-R-98-005
                                                   April 1998
RESOURCES
FOR THE FUTURE
Searching for the Profit in
Pollution Prevention:
                Case Studies in the Corporate
                Evaluation of Environmental
                Opportunities
                James Boyd
                Resources for the Future
     Environmental This report was created under a cooperative agreement
     Accounting    between Resources for the Future and the United States
     USEPAJ         Environmental Protection Agency.

-------
                       Funding Information and Disclaimer
This paper was prepared under Cooperative Agreement # CX824429-01 between EPA's Office of
Policy, Planning, and Evaluation (OPPE) and Resources for the Future.  The OPPE Project Officers
were William L. Schroeer and Bob Noland.

The paper was funded and managed by the Environmental Accounting Project, a program of EPA's
Office of Pollution Prevention and Toxics. The Environmental Accounting Project works with a
wide variety of industrial organizations, academic and research institutions, and other partners to
encourage and motivate businesses to understand the full spectrum  of environmental costs and
incorporate these costs into decision-making. To obtain additional copies of this report or other
environmental accounting resources, visit the Project's website at www.epa.gov/opptintr/acctg, or
contact EPA's Pollution Prevention Information Clearinghouse at (202) 260-1023 or via e-mail at
ppic@epamail.epa.gov.

Although this  document was developed under a grant from the U.S. Environmental Protection
Agency to Resources for  the Future, the findings, ideas,  and views contained herein do not
necessarily reflect those of the Agency, and no official endorsement should be inferred.

This research was  initiated to more fully illuminate the challenges facing industry in the adoption
of pollution prevention (P2) opportunities,  and to identify issue areas that can be studied and
addressed by policy-makers  and industry.  The  case studies in this paper describe three P2 projects
that were chosen for analysis precisely because they were in some -way  unsuccessful. This analysis,
based on a small and non-random sampling, is not necessarily representative of the experiences of
all companies or all P2 investment possibilities.

-------
         Searching for the Profit in Pollution Prevention:
            Case Studies in the Corporate Evaluation
                 of Environmental Opportunities*
                             James Boyd
                      Resources for the Future
                             April, 1998
   * This research was funded by the Office of Pollution Prevention and Toxics, United
States Environmental Protection Agency.  Special thanks are due Susan McLaughlin (EPA),
Bill Bilkovich, Ric Olson (Dow), Max McCombs (Solutia), Larry McCune (Flexsys), and
Daniel Juers (DuPont) for their invaluable assistance in providing information and defining
the issues addressed by this study.

-------

-------
                                  CONTENTS
Executive Summary	1

1.  Introduction	5

2.  Design of the Study	9

3.  The Cases  	,	11

    Dow  	11

    Monsanto  	23

    DuPont  	35

4.  Information and the Financial Evaluation of Pollution Prevention Opportunities . . 45

    Are environment-related financial benefits being captured
       appropriately by the decision-making process?  	45

    Are firms missing win-win pollution prevention opportunities?	48

    Information barriers and the search for clear financial benchmarks
       of P2 profitability  	49

5.  Conclusion: Pollution Prevention and Public Policy  	55
References
58

-------

-------
                             Executive Summary
Project Overview

   The concept of pollution prevention, or "P2," is emblematic of a new, proactive
environmental mindset that promises more sustainable industrial management. By targeting
the causes, rather than the consequences,  of polluting  activity, P2  seeks to eliminate
pollutants at their source and thereby avoid the need to treat or dispose of those pollutants
later. The P2 concept has given rise to talk of win-win opportunities in which innovation and
new ways of thinking will lead to waste reduction and, at the same time, make firms money
by reducing  costs or stimulating new products.  Unfortunately,  the vision of pollution
prevention as a set of win-win opportunities is somewhat at odds with actual corporate
experience. While anecdotal evidence from a  number of studies suggests that such
opportunities exist and that many firms have pursued them, proponents say the pace of P2
is too slow and that the private sector is somehow failing to see opportunities in front of it.

   Very little is actually known about how and why, in the real world, firms pursue or do
not pursue pollution prevention.  To address this deficit, this report presents case studies of
P2-related decisions made at three different firms,  all global chemical manufacturers
headquartered in the United States. A particular type of business activity was sought for
analysis.

   First, the investment or product marketing effort had to involve a pollution prevention
opportunity. Pollution prevention was defined as a new product or process thaTallowed for
pollutant source reductions or that involved in-process recycling.  Second, the investment
or marketing opportunity had to be promising enough to be technically and financially
evaluated by the firms themselves. Third, the investments or product had to be in some way
"unsuccessful." That is, the firms chose to not invest in the product or process changes, or
investment was significantly delayed, pending  the  resolution of market, technical, or
regulatory uncertainties.  For the purposes of this project, unsuccessful P2 opportunities are
of greatest interest because they allow us to focus on the corporate rationale for not making
P2 investments.  Fourth, the study sought projects with a capital, technical, or marketing
"scale" sufficient to ensure a certain degree of complexity to  the decision.   Finally, the
analysis required the participating firms to provide detailed, often proprietary, data on the
projects considered.

    The cases open a window onto business decision-making generally, and environmental
decision-making specifically.  They allow for a deeper understanding of the  relationship
between pollution prevention and corporate profitability. It should be noted, of course, that
three,  non-randomly selected cases cannot be used to  draw broad policy or  empirical

-------
conclusions. Instead, they should be viewed as a lesson on the practical challenges facing
private sector managers.  Regulators, policymakers, and other corporate managers can
presumably benefit from a better practical understanding of corporate P2 decision-making.

   The cases shed light on the following types of questions: Are firms really passing up P2
opportunities that could save them money? Do firms' current financial and accounting
practices treat environmental investments differently from other investments? What hurdles
must P2 investments clear?  Do firms evaluate P2 opportunities in a defensible manner, or
are there persistent organizational biases against P2, perhaps due to inappropriate accounting
procedures or incentive schemes? Are there unambiguous financial benchmarks that can be
used as a guide to which P2 projects should go forward?

   The cases  reveal the kinds of technical, regulatory, and informational issues that are
likely to face any firm contemplating P2 innovations. While based on a very limited sample,
the evidence contradicts the view that firms suffer from an inability to appreciate profitable
P2 investments. Using concepts from business and financial theory to analyze the decisions
that were made, the study concludes that the investments were financially unattractive
because of significant unresolved technical  difficulties, uncertain market conditions, and, in
some cases, regulatory barriers or insufficient emissions enforcement. In many cases, the
mystery of why a P2 opportunity was not successful can be resolved simply by taking a
closer look at the costs, benefits, and risks involved.

Principles Illustrated by the Cases

   The cases concretely illustrate a set of more general principles relating to the technical,
regulatory, and financial challenges facing P2 project evaluation and implementation.

1. Technical issues
   P2 projects  will often present complex technical challenges that have important
implications for financial analysis.

       In complex manufacturing operations,  even a relatively small pollution prevention
      process change may require changes in a whole set of interrelated processes.  If so,
       the pollution prevention option cannot be analyzed financially without a technical,
      financial, and regulatory analysis of these other required process changes.

Moreover, firms must often bear costs in order to estimate the costs of potential new projects.

       Formal financial analysis may in some cases be moot, if technical uncertainties
       associated with the project cannot themselves be resolved at reasonable cost.

-------
Before financial analysis can occur, the firm must be able to identify the new technologies
and processes that will be required by the project.  In order to come to that specification,
however, numerous questions must be answered.

2. The implications of uncertainty
      Uncertainties, whether market-related, technical or regulatory, can fundamentally
alter the economics of a project decision.  For instance, uncertainty can in some cases create
an incentive to delay action.

       With some investments,  there is value in the delay of a project decision.  Delay
      allows for resolution of uncertainties and the avoidance of irreversible, and
      potentially wasted, investments.

In economic parlance, there  may be a significant "option value" to delayed investment
arising from unresolved uncertainties.

3. Regulatory pressure and regulatory barriers
      Effective  regulatory  enforcement  may be important  to the  development and
marketing of P2 products. Meaningful monitoring and compliance efforts, particularly those
directed at under-regulated firms, increase the financial value of new products that provide
P2 solutions.

      Existing effluent standards can act as a powerful motivator for pollution prevention
       by creating markets for technologies that can address firms' compliance issues.

While effective regulatory enforcement is in some cases central to the creation of markets
for P2, some forms of regulation can stand in the way of P2.

      In some cases, regulatory rules can raise the costs of supplying and using pollution
      prevention technologies.  This can have the unintended consequence of inhibiting the
      diffusion of technologies with desirable environmental characteristics.

The desire  to experiment with P2 innovation is  often  thwarted  by rigid media- and
technology-specific regulations.

4. The (unsuccessful) search for clear financial benchmarks of P2 profitability
      Financial  analysis of any  investment is as  much  an art as it is a science.  The
complexity of factors employed in a sound investment analysis and incomplete information
regarding future market, regulatory, and technical conditions  mean that  calculations of
financial return need to be viewed with caution and sophistication. For instance,

      Accounting techniques must be  evaluated in order to determine whether reported
       benchmark figures (such as rate of return) are viewed by management insiders as

-------
       complete and unbiased. Managers are likely to better understand the ways in which
       their own analyses are biased.  If so, benchmark figures must be interpreted with
       care, particularly by outside analysts.

While the "rate of return" to P2 projects  seems a natural metric of desirability, even that
measure must be weighed against a larger set of factors.

       Rate of return is relevant only as  it compares to a project's cost of capital.
       Moreover, the cost of capital is not typically easy to measure, since it is intimately
       related to project risk. Thus, the implication of a particular rate of return figure for
       decision-making requires detailed knowledge of factors contributing to risk.

No single rate of return "hurdle" can be used as a benchmark for judging an investment's
profitability.

Conclusions and Implications for Public Policy

       Rather than organizational barriers  or myopia, the cases reveal a set of complex but
ultimately rational motivations for the decisions made by managers. Appreciation of those
motivations is important because it can  help guide public- and private-sector efforts to
improve corporate America's pollution prevention performance.

       This analysis' conclusions  should not be taken as either a defense or condemnation
of the firms'  environmental performance.  The "right" level of pollution prevention to be
undertaken by the corporate sector is a question left to a different study (though it is worth
emphasizing that regulations, and the avoidance of regulatory costs, were in all the cases a
"driver" that motivated the firms' search for pollution prevention). Still, without a detailed
accounting of social benefits and costs, little can be said about whether more or less stringent
regulation was appropriate hi these cases.  Instead, the cases say much more about the way
in which firms are regulated.

       The report advocates more extensive experimentation with flexible, "performance-
based" regulations. P2 increasingly calls for firms to engage in the redesign of complex
products and processes in ever-changing product markets.  Performance-based regulations,
which allow greater latitude for technological experimentation via product and process
reconfiguration, will enhance the expected financial value of truly innovative approaches to
pollution prevention.

-------
 1.  Introduction

        For the last 25 years environmental regulation and private sector environmental
 management have focused on end-of-pipe emission reductions and remediation of existing
 soil, air, and water pollution problems.  This "compliance-driven" approach to regulation
 was largely dictated by the scope of environmental problems left by decades of relatively
 unhindered industrial production and the urgency of legal and institutional reforms needed
 to foster improvements. With significant environmental improvements, however, has come
 a greater emphasis on more forward-looking and flexible environmental strategies. Instead
 of  reacting to pollution that is about to be (or already is) released to the environment,
 regulators and the private sector are turning to environmental strategies that target the causes,
 rather than the consequences, of polluting activity. "Pollution prevention" (P2) is at the heart
 of this new prospective mindset.  Pollution prevention seeks the most direct resolution of
 environmental problems ~ the elimination of pollutants via source reduction or recycling
 before treatment or disposal become issues.

       Pollution prevention is a challenge for the private sector because it requires diverse
 forms of  innovation.  Pollution prevention can require the redesign of products,  the
 reconfiguration of manufacturing processes, and the realignment of supplier and customer
 relationships. Because innovation is difficult,  often costly, and inherently uncertain, firms
 must also find new ways of integrating environmental concerns into the corporate  planning
 process.  This paper seeks to illuminate the way in  which firms are confronting these
 challenges. Through the use of case studies, the paper provides a window into the corporate
 evaluation of opportunities for P2 innovation.

       The way in which the private sector approaches pollution prevention is pertinent to
 a large set of ongoing environmental policy debates. Calls for pollution prevention are at the
 center of a broad regulatory and corporate movement. Information-based programs such as
the Toxics Release  Inventory and  experiments with flexible regulation, such  as those
 associated with the Common Sense Initiative and Project XL, are united by their ultimate
goal of pollution prevention.1 Within the private sector, there is talk of "sustainable corporate
environmental management," which inevitably centers on firms' ability to prevent, rather
   The Pollution Prevention Act of 1990 was the first federal legislation geared toward fostering this new way
of thinking. It has been accompanied by state-led legislation and programs and calls for further federal
legislation. These statutory approaches are diverse, but they all attempt to motivate pollution prevention via
a combination of information disclosure, mandatory prevention planning, and voluntary commitments. For
an overview of the history and current status of the pollution prevention movement, see EPA (1997). Another
good summary document is Freeman, et al (1992).

-------
than treat or dispose of waste.2  A commonly expressed belief within this movement is that
pollution prevention is a "win-win" corporate strategy. In this view, innovation and new
ways of thinking will lead to waste reduction, and at the same time, make firms money by
reducing costs or stimulating new products.3

        Pollution prevention, cast as both a corporate and an environmental benefit, has
ignited hope in less adversarial environmental regulation.  It has  also created optimism in the
private sector's ability to come up with low-cost solutions to their environmental problems.
Unfortunately, the vision  of pollution prevention  as  a  set of win-win opportunities is
somewhat at odds with perceptions of actual corporate behavior.  While anecdotal evidence
suggests that win-win opportunities exist, and have been pursued by many firms, there is
some frustration that the pace of change is inadequate.

        The idea that pollution prevention can save firms money, but that they nevertheless
neglect these opportunities, colors debate over regulatory reforms geared toward pollution
prevention.  For some, it calls into question the desirability of regulatory reforms often
associated with pollution prevention, such as regulatory flexibility.   If firms cannot be
counted on to make environmental improvements that save them money, the argument goes,
then only the blunt instrument of command and control regulation can be counted on to get
the job done.4 Others undoubtedly consider failures to invest in profit-making pollution
prevention a further example of corporate environmental intransigence.

        Another line of thinking holds that "organizational barriers" account for firms' failure
to be aware of and pursue win-win  investments.  Organizational barriers may arise, for
example, due to  information barriers,  accounting-based  distortions, or inappropriate
  2 DuPont claims that over the last 10 years the company has shifted its environmental technology effort from
 85 percent investment in pollution control to 60-70 percent investment in "green" products and pollution
 prevention (Pelley, 1997,138).

   3 Barry Commoner expresses the view as follows: "The strategy of prevention cures the conflict between
 environmental quality and economic development that is inherent in the control strategy... Properly designed,
 the productive investments engendered by the strategy of prevention could trigger a much-needed economic
 renaissance" (Commoner, 1994,217).

   4 One analysis of waste reduction at chemical plants concluded that waste reduction was brought about in
 some cases only when required by regulation to do so, but that the plants found the measure to be "cost-
 effective once in practice" (Sarokin et al, 1985).  This type of result  suggests that command and control
 regulations, in some cases, lead to both lower private sector costs and improved environmental quality and that
 private sector managers were unable to identify the opportunity themselves.
        For a recent study with a similar overall perspective, see the NRDC study referred to in section 3
 of this paper (Greer and van Loben Sels, 1997).

-------
 managerial incentive schemes.5 The policy implications of this perspective point toward
 regulatory assistance or requirements focused on internal management and accounting
 processes.

        For their part, corporate environmental managers tend to be more skeptical of
 pollution prevention's profitability.6  They point to regulatory barriers that reduce the
 financial incentive to change production processes or introduce new products with uncertain
 regulatory mandates.

        Much' of this debate hinges on whether pollution prevention can actually be counted
 on to save firms money. Consider the implications of evidence that companies fail to pursue
 pollution prevention  opportunities that would profit them. First, this evidence would lend
 credence to the argument that regulations should mandate pollution prevention.7 Second, it
 would point toward the need to reform private sector capital budgeting, accounting, and
 environmental management techniques to overcome organizational barriers to P2. If, on the
 other hand, pollution prevention's economic benefits are overstated, a different set of issues
 arises for regulators  and firms.  If firms do not pursue pollution prevention because it is
 simply not profitable to do so, attention should be focused on factors that contribute to the
 difficulty, cost, and benefit of implementing P2 innovations. Perhaps environmental costs
 are not being adequately imposed on the firms  creating them.  Perhaps technical assistance
 and government R&D could be used to lower technical barriers.  Or perhaps regulatory
 reforms should be used to lower regulatory barriers to P2 product and process changes.

        These issues are of central importance to the future of environmental regulation.
 Unfortunately, very  little is known about why - in the real world - firms pursue or do not
      As an example, Porter (1995, 131) suggests that assignment of environmental issues to corporate
departments without full profit responsibility leads to excessively narrow and incremental decisions. He also
suggests that firms use inappropriately high hurdle rates to screen environmental investments.

     Evidence on the profitability of P2 opportunities is decidedly mixed. For instance, an Environmental
Protection Agency study (EPA, 1992) evaluated a broad set of source reduction options at a large-scale
petroleum refinery. Most of the options were found to have negative rates of return and only one had a rate
of return higher than the historical rate of return for projects at the refinery. This type of evidence runs counter
to the hope that there are plentiful, undiscovered, win-win P2 opportunities. However, the EPA also has been
able to develop an extensive set of case studies depicting P2 successes. For examples see the Environmental
Accounting Project's web site (www.epa.gov/opptintr/acctg).

   7 The  state of New Jersey has pioneered mandatory P2 planning. A study of New Jersey's experience
suggests that mandatory planning leads to more ambitious corporate P2 goals and can help reveal opportunities
for cost savings (Natan, et al, 1996).

-------
pursue pollution prevention opportunities. The case studies presented in this paper seek to
fill that void by analyzing real-life pollution prevention investment decisions. The first two
cases deal with investments that did not survive their firms' capital budgeting process. The
third involves difficulties associated with a pollution prevention product being marketed to
a large group of commercial customers (who themselves are deciding whether to invest in
pollution prevention). With the  cases, the study hopes to shed light on private  sector
environmental decision-making.  In turn, this will shed light on the ways in which  public
policy can best promote pollution prevention.

-------
2. Design of the Study

       The study centers on pollution prevention initiatives at three different firms, all global
chemical manufacturers headquartered in the United States. A particular type of business
activity was sought for analysis.

       First, the investment or product marketing effort had to involve a pollution prevention
opportunity. Pollution prevention was defined as a new product or process that allowed for
pollutant source reductions or that involved in-process recycling. Environmental benefits
had to come from these types of innovations, not from new disposal or treatment methods.

       Second, the investment or marketing opportunity had to be promising enough to be
evaluated by the firms themselves.  More specifically, the opportunity had to involve not
only technical, but also financial, analysis.  The financial analysis is critical. Even if a
pollution prevention technology passes muster in engineering labs or environmental health
and safety meetings, it will not succeed in a practical sense unless  it survives a firm's
strategic analysis and capital budgeting process. Strategic and  financial analysis is the key
corporate decision-making nexus. It is the decision-making activity during which the widest
variety of internal corporate expertise is brought to bear to evaluate costs, rewards, and risks.
What types of information are collected? How is the information used? Since investment
analysis is the principal information-processing function of a corporation, firms' investment
analyses are the best place to look for answers.

       Third, the investments or product had to be in some way "unsuccessful."  That is, the
firms  chose to not invest in the product or process changes, or investment was significantly
delayed, pending the resolution of market, technical, or regulatory uncertainties.  For the
purposes of this project, unsuccessful P2 opportunities are of greatest interest because they
allow us to focus on the corporate rationale for not making P2 investments.

       Fourth, the study sought projects with a capital, technical, or marketing "scale"
sufficient to ensure a certain degree of complexity to the decision.  P2 opportunities on a
smaller scale (e.g., equipment purchases, certain chemical substitutions, general shop-floor
housekeeping) are important, and may be easier to achieve, but lack the complex range of
factors that impact large-scale business decisions.

       Finally, the  analysis required the participating firms to provide detailed, often
proprietary, data on the investments considered. Only with this  level of detail was a full
portrayal of the decisions possible.

-------
       The cases  open  a window onto  business decision-making  generally,  and
environmental decision-making specifically.  They allow for a deeper understanding of the
relationship between pollution prevention and corporate profitability.  It should be noted, of
course, that three, non-randomly selected cases cannot be used to  draw broad policy or
empirical conclusions.  Instead, they should be viewed as a lesson on the practical challenges
facing private sector managers. Regulators, policymakers, and other corporate managers can
presumably benefit from a better practical understanding of corporate P2 decision-making.
The cases shed light on the following types  of questions.  Are firms really passing up
opportunities that save them money? Do firms' current financial and accounting practices
treat environmental investments differently from other investments? What hurdles must P2
investments clear? Do firms evaluate P2 opportunities in a defensible manner, or are there
persistent organizational biases against P2,  perhaps due  to  inappropriate accounting
procedures or incentive schemes? The cases reveal the kinds of technical, regulatory, and
informational issues that are likely to face any firm contemplating P2 innovations.

       The paper is organized as follows.  The next section presents the three case studies.
Section 4 draws more general lessons from the cases, and in particular focuses on the effect
of information constraints on P2 decision-making.  Section 5 concludes and addresses the
question of how regulation and public policy can best promote private sector pollution
prevention.
                                         10

-------
 3.  The Cases

       This section presents three case studies of pollution prevention decision-making. The
 three firms whose P2 initiatives were analyzed are, in order of presentation, Dow Chemical,
 Monsanto, and DuPont.

 Dow

 The Facility

       The Dow facility, part of its polyurethane business, is a chemicals manufacturing
 plant located in La Porte, Texas, with annual revenues that exceed $350 million per year.
 The facility manufactures methylene diamine diisocyanate (MDI), the primary input to
 polyurethane foam and thermoplastic products.  Based on TRI reporting data, the plant's
 emissions are primarily to the air, with smaller amounts being released to water.

       The plant releases roughly 300,000 pounds of waste and incinerates, in a thermal
 oxydizing unit (TOX), roughly 2.5 million pounds of TRI-reported waste annually. The
 principal constituents of the incinerated  waste stream  are phosgene,  methanol, and
 monochlorobenzene (MCB).

 The Pollution Prevention Opportunity

       In  1995 and 1996  Dow participated in a collaborative  study with the Natural
 Resources Defense Council to identify pollution prevention opportunities at the La Porte
 plant. Assisted by an expert in the identification of P2 opportunities, the Dow-NRDC project
 identified  an  opportunity for  in-process recycling of  MCB.    MCB  recycling  is
 environmentally beneficial since the incineration of MCB creates "products of incomplete
 combustion." Recycling would eliminate these emissions.  The quantity of emissions avoided
 was not quantified by the study, but was assumed to be environmentally significant.

       This environmental "win" is accompanied by a potential economic "win" for Dow.
 The ability to  recycle — rather than incinerate — MCB  creates the possibility that the
 facility's incinerator can either be shut down or removed from its status as a RCRA-regulated
 boiler.8 Retirement of the incinerator would eliminate some operating costs.  However, the
   Note that there is an "extreme" TOX option ~ total shutdown — and an "intermediate" option -- conversion
to  non-RCRA status.  The intermediate option creates a broader set of technical options for the firm.
Specifically, the TOX could remain a viable disposal alternative for wastes that do not have a RCRA
designation.
                                        11

-------
primary benefit derives from avoidance of incinerator retrofitting costs associated with new
MACT and participate standards expected to be issued in 1999 or 2000. Shut-down, or the
incinerator's conversion to a non-RCRA unit, would allow Dow to avoid millions in
incinerator upgrade costs associated with these new, tougher standards.

Process Changes Associated with TOX Elimination

       The recycling of MCB is a necessary, but not sufficient, condition for the elimination
of the La Porte incinerator. A complicating factor is that a variety of waste streams are
incinerated in the TOX.9  TOX shutdown requires new forms of disposal for the non-MCB
wastes otherwise sent to the TOX.  In other words, the economic benefit of recycled MCB --
TOX retirement -- is contingent on the technical feasibility and cost of a host of other process
changes. As an example,  consider the phosgene waste stream. If not incinerated in the TOX,
phosgene must be source-reduced, treated via scrubber, or recycled.  Each of these options
presents unique technical  challenges, has uncertain  costs, and may create regulatory issues.
All of these must be evaluated in order to determine the costs and feasibility of diverting that
single waste stream from the TOX.

       The Dow-NRDC  group realized that TOX elimination was the primary, but not the
only,  potential source of financial benefit.10 While recycled MCB was the pollution
prevention opportunity,  TOX elimination was the economic driver.  The study group
therefore targeted a "TOX elimination project" for analysis. This project was mirrored by a
Business Opportunity Plan (BOP) initiated  by  Dow to evaluate the project's technical,
economic, and regulatory feasibility.

       From a business  standpoint, recycled MCB alone is  not a win-win opportunity. A
win-win investment is possible only if MCB is recycled and the other TOX waste streams
are source-reduced, recycled, or diverted to other modes of disposal. It is this "bundle" of
process changes that Dow must evaluate financially. The MCB recycling option cannot be
analyzed financially without a technical, financial, and regulatory analysis of the other waste
streams diverted from the TOX. This may seem obvious, but it is a point worth emphasizing.
  9 In addition to MCB, the TOX incinerates, in measurable quantities, methanol, phenyl isocyanate, phosgene,
carbon monoxide, carbon tetrachloride, and chloroform.

   10 Note the following terminological convention used in this analysis.  "Environmental benefits" denote
beneficial changes in environmental quality brought about by a process or product change, or other decision.
"Financial benefits" relate to the dollar value of those changes to the firm itself. For example, environmental
benefits can create financial benefits by reducing a firm's expected liability costs.
                                         12

-------
       In complex manufacturing operations, even a relatively small pollution prevention
       process change may require changes in a whole set of interrelated processes. If so,
       the pollution prevention option cannot be analyzed financially -without a technical,
       financial, and regulatory analysis of these other required process changes.

Financial analysis of the TOX elimination project requires estimation of the aggregate costs
of all waste stream process changes.

The Preliminary Financial Analysis

       In 1996  Dow's polyurethane business was presented with a financial  analysis
associated with the P2 project. Cash flows were estimated for several options, including
continued use of the TOX for all existing waste streams, continued use of the TOX but with
removal of RCRA waste streams, and total TOX elimination.11 Sound managerial accounting
techniques were employed: The accounting exercise featured standard discounting methods,
a  10-year time horizon, an estimated dollar benefit associated with avoided repermitting
costs, and the inclusion  of a relatively rich set of capital items associated with process
reconfiguration.

       The results  of the financial  analysis were encouraging in at least one  respect.
Depending on assumptions, rates of return for the MCB-recycle and TOX elimination option
were estimated to be as high as 70%. Even more encouraging from a financial standpoint
was the RCRA declassification option.  This option had an estimated 135% rate of return,
though keeping the TOX in non-RCRA operation was acknowledged as an environmental
negative. While the recommendation of the La Porte site's management team was to pursue
RCRA declassification, headquarters management never considered this to be a serious
option due to its questionable environmental implications.

       When presented with the options, more senior management opted to delay a decision
on the project.  The reasoning behind this decision is explored in greater depth below. Before
doing so, however, it deserves emphasis that the cash flow estimates in the existing financial
analysis are very preliminary.  While sound accounting techniques were employed, the cost
estimates are highly speculative.  Thus, the principal value of the firm's preliminary financial
analysis is that it identifies technical and regulatory issues that the firm must still resolve.
Its value as an accurate prediction of the project's expected value is much smaller.
   These cash flow estimates were derived using the expertise of engineers at La Porte, as well as regulatory
and engineering personnel at Dow headquarters.
                                        13

-------
Why Has the TOX Elimination Project Not Been Pursued?

       Dow's polyurethane business group has considered and rejected the investment
proposal twice.  Why?  Given the strongly positive rate of return estimate from Dow's
internal financial analysis, the decision to not move forward is initially puzzling. It is less
puzzling when the speculative nature of the analysis is considered.  The economic and
technical data available to  Dow suggests  that the project's profitability remains highly
uncertain.  Given its underlying technical and financial characteristics, the project's delay
is not particularly surprising.  The case  highlights a  relatively prosaic reason for the
investment's lack of success:  P2 innovation can be costly and create a set of complex
technical challenges.

       To explore the project's profitability, it is natural to organize the analysis on the basis
of the project's costs and its financial benefits.  Costs arise from the need to divert waste
streams from the TOX. Benefits arise from the ability to retire the TOX itself, at least as a
RCRA-permitted unit. Analysis of the case indicates that technical and regulatory challenges
present uncertain and potentially significant capital and human resource costs.  At the same
time, the project's financial benefit is uncertain.

       Technical Uncertainties. This section provides a more detailed description of the
non-MCB waste streams that would have to be diverted, were the TOX retired.  For each
waste stream  there is typically a set of options for reduction, disposal,  recycling, or sale.
While somewhat technical, the discussion should also give a flavor for the technical and
economic complexity of the project's evaluation.

       Methanol Meihanol at the La Porte facility, due to its ignitability characteristics, is
a RCRA-regulated waste stream. Options for this stream include (1) out-of-process recycling
(i.e., sale to another plant or firm); (2) burning off-site; or (3) in a different 'clean fuel' boiler
on-site.12

       The recycling option has attractive economic and environmental characteristics.
However, the La Porte manufacturing process contaminates the methanol with impurities that
render it unsuitable for most other commercial uses.   This creates an as-yet unresolved
technical problem.  How and at what cost can the methanol be decontaminated? Also,  a
customer for the methanol must be found. The off-site burn options require the identification
of an alternative incinerator and, like the recycling option, require transportation off-site.
   12 The team also considered the possibility that methanol could be eliminated from the process entirely. This
 was ultimately determined to be technically infeasible.
                                          14

-------
 Also, off-site incineration is typically much more expensive than on-site incineration.13 The
 use of methanol as a fuel in an on-site boiler was not evaluated extensively enough to resolve
 whether or not this was a viable option.

       Liquids colkctedfrom absorption units. Much of the MCB to be recycled at La Porte
 is originally collected in "pressure swing adsorption units" (PSAs).  For the MCB to be
 recycled, however, it must first be decontaminated. Decontamination creates a host of
 technical issues relating to how and when the stream becomes contaminated. The MCB is
 contaminated with water and chlorinated impurities in undetermined concentration.

       Resolution of these issues has important consequences for the process' redesign. If
 the chlorinated impurities are present in low enough concentration, then the water can be
 removed and the MCB reused. This  is the most desirable outcome financially, since it
 simply requires the installation of a molecular sieve for water removal.  If chlorinated
 impurities are present in sufficient quantity, however, they must be removed since their
 buildup significantly affects the efficiency of the production process.

       If removal of chlorinated impurities is required there are three basic options. At a
 cost of  $1 million a  new  distillation column, dedicated  to  impurity removal, can be
 constructed. It is clearly desirable to avoid this cost.  There are two possible ways to do so,
 but each with their own technical uncertainties. If contamination arises during one particular
 stage of the process, then an existing column could be used for decontamination. Process
 analysis is required for this issue to be resolved. If contamination is introduced elsewhere,
 a different column could possibly be used. The technical question in this case is whether that
 column could be used to do "double-duty" distillation.

       Phenyl isocyanate.  Phenyl isocyanate (phenco) is a stream with some source
 reduction  potential (an  option currently being  pursued at LaPorte).   However, total
 elimination via source reduction is not expected to be possible.  Recycling has also been
 considered, though the nature and removability of contaminants in the phenco stream is an
unresolved issue.  The most viable option is transport off-site for sale or incineration. The
primary  technical issue in this case is how to lower  transportation risks.  Phenco has
"reactive"  properties that make it unstable  for transportation.  A possible, but untested
technical fix is to react the phenco with waste polyols, to form an inert foam.  If successful,
this technique would render phenco safer for transport.
     Off-site incineration costs can exceed on-site costs by a factor often.  See "Combustors Said to Face
Uncertain Future with MACT Standards, Market Overcapacity," Environment Reporter, Vol 28, no. 7, June
13,1997, p. 307-308.
                                         15

-------
       Carbon tetrachloride and chloroform.  Carbon tetrachloride and chloroform are
contaminants in the MCB stream. In order for MCB to be recycled, they must be distilled
and burned off-site. (As contaminants in the MCB stream they are currently incinerated in
the TOX). Removal via distillation column is the only alternative. Treatment of this stream
is not problematic technically, though investment in a distillation column is an expense.  And
off-site incineration creates transportation risks and increases disposal costs.

       Products from an organic recovery system. La Porte has an organic  compounds
recovery system (ORS) to treat groundwater contamination caused by a previous owner of
the site. MCB is a prime constituent of this waste stream.  Recycling requires this MCB to
be captured via a PSA unit. There are three possible PSA solutions.   First, there  is an
existing PSA unit used to backup the TOX.  This unit is relatively old, however, and its
remaining life is uncertain.  Second, there is another existing PSA on-site that could possibly
be used.  Use of this unit is uncertain because of questions regarding whether or not it can
handle the air volume created by the  ORS. Also, there is a significant capital cost associated
with connecting this PSA to the organic recovery system.  Third, a new, dedicated PSA for
ORS vapors could be constructed.  There is also a non-PSA solution. ORS vapors could
potentially be burned in the TOX if it were converted to non-RCRA status (though see
discussion of regulatory issues below).

       Phosgene.  Phosgene is produced on-site and used as a reactant in the production
process.  There are two removal options.  First, use of an existing scrubber unit, currently
used as a safety backup. Technical upgrade of this unit to a primary mitigation device would
be required. Second, phosgene could be incinerated in the TOX if it is converted to non-
RCRA status (phosgene is not a RCRA waste stream). Also, the possibility that phosgene
could be recycled was considered.  The technology for doing so is largely undefined.

       Waste  water treatment plant salinity. La Porte has a waste water treatment plant
(WWTP) that relies partially on the TOX as a source of water.  If the TOX is eliminated, the
TOX water stream may no longer be available to the WWTP, an issue discussed below.
Without this water, the salinity of the WWTP increases. This is problematic since the plant's
biological treatment system is  calibrated to a particular level of salinity. Without that
balance, its effectiveness as an organic removal system is reduced, which creates a possible
compliance problem.  Thus, a technical solution would be required that allows  for salt
reduction. Alternatively, the plant would require increased  freshwater use, which creates
regulatory issues of its own (see below).

       Regulatory Uncertainties. Regulation raises often complex technical and financial
questions, questions that must be resolved before the financial implications of a  process
                                         16

-------
change can be clear.  Several of the process changes required for TOX elimination raised
regulatory issues.

       The capture ofMCB.  MCB vapor from the ORS system is  currently being burned
in the TOX.  Because it is introduced to the TOX as a vapor, it is not RCRA-regulated.
However, if MCB from the ORS is to be recycled, it would be captured as a liquid. If this
MCB contained any impurities subject to RCRA regulation, these impurities in liquid form
could prohibit their incineration in a non-RCRA TOX.

       Phenco stabilization. Regulatory approval may have to be sought if phenco is to be
combined with waste polyols.  The rationale for this combination is to increase the stability
of phenco, making it safer for transport. It is not clear, however, that this stabilization
approach would  be permissible.  Regulatory approval  is not guaranteed, and in any case
would have to be requested.  The combination of two different forms of hazardous waste
creates a regulatory issue that would have to be resolved.

       Phosgene treatment. For phosgene, the TOX has a higher "treatment efficiency" than
would the phosgene scrubber alternative. Because Texas has an "anti-backsliding" rule, TOX
shutdown would require testing, monitoring,  and re-permitting of a scrubber-based phosgene
treatment system.

       Waste -water treatment plant salinity.  The TOX's regulatory permit currently requires
combustion gases  to be cooled and cleaned by water that is acquired from a freshwater
source.  This water does double-duty,  however, since  it is then sent to the  facility's
wastewater treatment plant. Plant managers are concerned that if the  TOX is eliminated they
may not be granted regulatory approval to draw this same freshwater stream. While TOX
elimination requires no net increase in freshwater use, the WWTP alone may not be viewed
as a justifiable use  of the water.

       Issues arising from transportation. Several of the options associated with TOX
elimination involve the  transportation off-site of non-MCB waste streams ~ specifically
methanol  and phenco. Taking waste streams off-site for sale or  incineration by another
firm's  facilities  raises liability concerns.  Use or disposal of wastes by other firms can
potentially tie Dow legally, via liability, to  environmental problems caused by those other
firms.  Firms that generate waste can be liable for damages due to use or disposal at other
firms'  sites.  This  is true even if the primary generator takes all  possible precautions in
transportation and has no control over the care taken by the firm to whom the waste is
transported. Transportation therefore exposes Dow to a set of risks over which it has
relatively less control.
                                        17

-------
       The pollution prevention opportunity at La Porte presents numerous technical and
regulatory  challenges.14  This has a number of implications for the project's financial
analysis.   What should be  clear is that the firm must  bear costs to  estimate costs.
Specifically, the firm must devote human resources to the solution of technical, market and
regulatory issues. Before financial analysis of the TOX elimination project can occur, the
firm must be able to identify the new technologies and processes that will be required by the
project.  In order to come to that specification,  however, numerous questions must be
answered. Can existing purification systems be used to treat different waste streams?  Is there
another firm in close geographic proximity that is willing to purchase (or be given) waste
methanol?  Will regulators allow the use of freshwater for a wastewater treatment plant in
the absence of the TOX, or must the firm "innovate around  the problem." These and other
questions must be answered  in order to define the technical specifications of the TOX
elimination project.

       Formal financial analysis may in some cases be moot,  if technical uncertainties
       associated with the project cannot themselves be resolved at reasonable cost.

These uncertainties have not all been resolved at the La Porte facility. One explanation for
the project's lack of success is that  it involved a set of process  changes that presented
significant technical and regulatory challenges.   ,

       The Option Value of Continued TOX Operation. Consider now the potential
benefits of the TOX elimination project. The recycling of MCB would allow for some raw
materials reductions (thus  reducing certain  input costs).   TOX shutdown would also
eliminate certain energy and labor costs associated with its operation.15 The principal benefit,
however, arises from the ability to avoid re-engineering, testing, and capital costs associated
with new RCRA permit requirements.  The La Porte TOX will be subject to new RCRA
rules that  promise more stringent  particulate  and new  "maximum available control
technology" (MACT) standards.

       Dow estimated a $4 million cost for the upgrades necessary to remain in compliance.
Thus, the economic benefit of TOX elimination is the avoidance of a potentially significant
upgrade bill. Several uncertainties cloud this estimate, however.
  14 The challenge was described by one participant as "managing 50 speculations at once."

  15 Of course, as noted above, there will be potentially off-setting labor, energy, materials, and technical costs
associated with the diversion from the TOX of non-MCB waste streams.
                                        18

-------
       First, the date at which compliance will be required is uncertain.  Currently, the
Environmental  Protection Agency has until November, 2000  to  promulgate the new
regulations. Following the rules announcement, an unspecified amount of time is allowed
for testing and upgrade. From a financial analysis standpoint, the timing of the requirements
is significant. The further in the future the requirements are put in effect, the less motivation
Dow has to eliminate the TOX today.16  This is due to the effects  of discounting. As is
explained elsewhere in this report, discounting implies a reduction in the value of benefits
(or costs) that arise in the future.  Specifically, a $4 million benefit in 3 or 4 years is worth
substantially less than a $4 million benefit today.  Delayed regulatory rulemaking thus
reduces the value of TOX elimination. Due to the effects of discounting, regulatory delay
in the case acts as a disincentive to invest in process change.

       More importantly, the technical requirements are not known as  of yet. This means
that, until the new standards are announced, the $4 million estimate is subject to upward or
downward revision.  This uncertainty creates an economic incentive to delay action on the
TOX elimination proposal. In economic parlance, there is an "option value" to delayed
investment. When investment decisions are not easily reversed there is an incentive to avoid
committing resources until uncertainties are resolved.

       As noted earlier, there are numerous technical and capital costs associated with the
diversion of the non-MCB waste streams.  Many, if not most, of these costs are irreversible
in the sense that they could not be recovered  if Dow decided in the future to re-open the
incinerator.17  Another way of putting this is that the commitment to TOX elimination
imposes "sunk" costs. When an investment has uncertain benefits and involves irreversible
investments, the use of conventional investment rules such as Net Present Value (NPV) can
be inappropriate. In these situations, NPV fails to capture the value of delaying the decision
(the "option value") until uncertainties can be resolved.  The TOX elimination project is an
example  of an investment situation in which the option value is likely to be large. It involves
significant, irreversible  costs and its benefits (the avoided upgrade cost) hinge on an
uncertainty that will be resolved in the not-too-distant future.

       With some investments, there is  value in the delay  of a project decision.  Delay
       allows for  resolution  of uncertainties and the avoidance of irreversible, and
       potentially wasted investments.
   16 Complicating the issue of timing, is EPA Region 6's "combustion initiative," which may allow for
accelerated permitting.  This is currently only a possibility for the La Porte facility, however.

  17 Actually, Dow management expresses a concern, based on their perception of current regulatory attitudes
toward incineration, that once closed, the TOX could never be re-opened.
                                         19

-------
       Finally, TOX elimination could lead to another lost option with potential value. In
the longer term, the La Porte plant may be used to produce different products with as-yet
unseen process characteristics. While a wholesale process reinvention is relatively unlikely
for the plant, it is worth noting that the TOX could be useful or necessary as part of such a
process re-configuration and that de-commissioning now could make re-configuration
impractical.

       Consider the following example. By deriving the option value of a delayed decision,
the example demonstrates that a positive NP V is not sufficient motivation for managers to
go ahead with a project.18 Assume the following: that for an investment of $2. 1 million the
firm could invest in new process technology, human resources, and testing and achieve
environmental benefits due to recycling.  The financial benefit would be due to avoided
retrofitting costs that are currently uncertain.  Two outcomes are possible, with equal
probability.  Either the avoided costs are $2 million or they are $6 million, depending on
regulatory requirements. Assume that the new compliance standard is announced in 3 years
and must be immediately implemented by the firm.

       Assuming the investment is made today, and discounting cash flows at a 10 percent
interest rate, the project's NPV is calculated as follows.19
NPV= -2.
                                     (l+.l)3
                                              = 904 =$904,000
The positive net present value would ordinarily suggest that the firm move forward with the
project.  However, we now calculate the present value of waiting to make the investment
decision until the regulatory standard is announced. By waiting, the firm can avoid making
the $2.1 million investment if the standard requires retrofitting changes that cost only $2
million. (The firm will not invest in this situation since it is clearly not in the firm's financial
interest to spend more to avoid a cost than the cost itself.)  Therefore, the firm will move
forward with the investment only if the regulatory standard implies the larger retrofitting
    18 The example is meant to be illustrative, rather than a numerically accurate depiction of the Dow
investment decision.

  19 The fractional term is the expected, and discounted, benefit of being able to avoid the upgrade cost in 3
years.
                                         20

-------
cost.  The NPV of delaying and making the investment only if avoided upgrade costs are
large is
                                             -]=1.464 =$1,464,000
The value of waiting is greater than the value of investing immediately.20 This is true for two
reasons. First, the firm can avoid the investment if the benefits turn out to be small.  Second,
the three year delay reduces the present value of the investment's cost.  As a result, the
option value of the delayed decision is $560,000, or the difference between the two NPVs.

       In addition to  the unresolved technical issues described earlier,  this  example
illustrates another reason for the Dow investment's failure to be approved. Given uncertain
regulatory standards and the irreversible nature of the investments necessary to  move to
alternatives to TOX-based disposal, a delayed decision is likely to be optimal.

Other Organizational and Strategic Issues

       Capital and human resource constraints have also played a role hi the decision to put
off the TOX project. Resolution of technical issues and regulatory uncertainties and relative
confidence in positive rate of return estimates is not sufficient to guarantee project success.
Typically, firms also prioritize their investment activities, pursuing those that offer the
highest rates of return on capital and human resources.  As is described elsewhere in this
report, capital rationing is a mechanism that helps firms prioritize.

       Capital  rationing has been a concrete issue for the La Porte investment.  In 1996
Dow's polyurethane business had an 86% hurdle rate for new capital projects. This rate can
be  explained by (1) a fixed (rationed) amount of new capital made available to the
polyurethane business by senior Dow management and (2) the existence of a competing
capital project within the business that offered a particularly high expected return.  Dow has
15 global business units, each with a limited amount of capital to be allocated in a given
year.  The competing project involved  a plant in Freeport, LA.  The Freeport project was
financially competitive relative to  La Porte, as well as competitive in terms of the
environmental benefits it promised.  The Freeport plant promised to eliminate 50 million
pounds of chlorinated organics by harnessing a new process chemistry, a P2 investment with
    To help understand the equation, note that with probability .5 the firm does not make the investment and
therefore bears no cost and receives no benefit.
                                        21

-------
environmental benefits an order of magnitude greater than that proposed at La Porte.21 Given
capital rationing, the La Porte investment was a relatively unappealing investment target.22

       The same can be said of investments in human capital.  Given the relative merits of
the Freeport investment, it is not surprising that human resources, particularly technical
expertise, were focused on that investment.  This had decidedly negative implications for the
La Porte investment.  Given the complexity of the technical issues that had to be resolved,
sustained problem-solving activity — which was dependent on the active involvement of
scarce personnel — was a prerequisite to moving forward with the TOX elimination project.
  21 This figure is speculative. Nevertheless, the magnitude of possible reductions is clearly significant.

  22 The question of why firms ration capital at all is explored in section 4.
                                         22

-------
Monsanto

The Product

       The Monsanto case involves a process that, at the time, was associated with its
Rubber Chemicals business unit. The firm was producing aminodiphenylamine (4-ADPA),
an intermediate product for the production of anti-oxidants, at plants in the U.S., Belgium,
and the United Kingdom. The final anti-oxidant product has a wide range of uses, but its
primary market is the world tire industry  where anti-oxidants  are used to improve tire
durability and safety.  The market for this product is  large and represented a significant
fraction of the Rubber Chemical unit's annual revenues.
                             /
       The existing process chemistry for 4-ADPA production used benzene, nitric acid, and
chlorine to produce nitrocholorobenzene (NCB).  NCB was then converted to 4-NDPA by
reaction with aniline. The 4-NDPA was in turn reacted with hydrogen to get the desired 4-
ADPA. The many process steps  leading to creation of the 4-ADPA intermediate product
required the disposal and handling of large quantities of chlorine. In addition, the process
created carbon monoxide, xylene air releases, and an aqueous waste stream contaminated
with inorganic salts. The process was the second-highest generator of waste in Monsanto's
Chemical Group. These environmental characteristics made the process a prime target for
process reinvention.

The Pollution Prevention Opportunity

       Beginning in the mid-8Os,  the Rubber Chemicals unit and Monsanto Corporate
Research began to explore alternatives to the process chemistry.  In 1991, chemists and
chemical engineers achieved a technical breakthrough with real promise: the possibility of
a process with virtually zero waste generation.  The innovation, dubbed ADPA, is a "direct
coupling" technology that eliminates the use of chlorine and several process steps in the
production of the 4-ADPA intermediate product.

       The project was granted a budget in excess of $10 million for development costs,
including the construction and operation of a fully-integrated pilot plant. By mid-1993 the
pilot plant had demonstrated the  technical efficacy, environmental benefits and potential
                                       23

-------
economic value of the new process. The environmental benefits of the new process were
significant and included
       • a 91% reduction in organic wastes
       • the virtual elimination of inorganic wastes, with total elimination of chlorine
       • waste water generation only 3% of its former total
       • greater chemical stability (significantly reduced risk of "runaway reactions")
       • the elimination of xylene emissions.23

       Another significant driver for the firm, however, were cost savings associated with
the process change.  The ADPA process required less than 50% of the old raw material
inputs and required fewer process steps. For these reasons, ADPA was projected to reduce
production costs by a magnitude virtually guaranteed to have a positive impact on profits and
market share. The firm had discovered a true "win-win" investment opportunity. In fact, the
technology's qualities were so obvious that commercial development was considered a "no-
brainer" by  Rubber Chemicals management.  Many of the process' benefits were never
quantified, simply because they were so large.  At least on a stand-alone basis, ADPA was
predicted to be a sure-fire success.  In light of this, it is noteworthy that Monsanto did not
choose to develop ADPA as part of its Rubber Chemicals business, due to major impacts on
integrated business units.  While ADPA was ultimately developed, its  transition from
prototype process to the commercial market was not immediate nor particularly smooth.

ADPA Today

       Today, the ADPA technology is owned and used in the production of anti-oxidants
by Flexsys, an independent, global rubber chemicals company, formed as a joint venture
between Monsanto and the Dutch firm Akzo Nobel. The formation of this new company was
central to ADPA's implementation  and  hints  at the complexities  surrounding the
technology's commercial development.  As we will see, issues well beyond the technology
and product itself complicated its implementation. Changes in Monsanto's strategic goals,
interrelationships between the 4-ADPA product line and other business units, and a set of
issues relating to divestiture and ownership of assets ultimately determined when and how
the technology would be brought into commercial use. Particularly because ADPA had such
clear benefits, the case underscores the complex tradeoffs that must be faced by managers
responsible for the evaluation and implementation of pollution prevention, or any other,
investment opportunities.
  23 Aggregate reductions were predicted to be significant. For a single plant, the numbers translated into a
56 million pounds per year reduction in chemical waste generation and a 1 billion pound per year reduction
in waste water requiring treatment.
                                        24

-------
Changing Markets and the Corporation's Strategic Goals

       The  ADPA story illustrates  the  way  in  which even a clear win-win process
improvement can be influenced by global market changes and the shifting strategic goals of
a multi-national firm.  The fate of ADPA was largely determined, not by the financial or
environmental benefits of the project itself, but by the fate of the larger rubber chemicals
business in which it was embedded and the other Monsanto businesses with which it was
integrated.

       A shift in strategic goals. In the early 1990s, CEO Richard Mahoney was looking for
a way to improve Monsanto's stock performance and position the firm to take advantage of
changes in world chemical markets. One of his strategies was to announce a new corporate
financial goal: specifically,  a 20  percent return on equity (ROE).24 Mahoney's financial
advisors had studied the broader market and determined that firms in the top quartile of stock
performance (measured by the price-earnings ratio) were those which consistently met a 20
percent ROE.25 In effect, then, a 20 percent ROE was chosen as a proxy for "improved stock
performance."  A likely reason is that ROE  provides a relatively  concrete target for
managerial decision-making. ROE is a standard accounting measure, and thus a convenient
yardstick with which to compare business lines and judge capital investments.26 Thus, the
20 percent ROE target was designed  to motivate a shift in Monsanto's businesses toward
markets and products that offered greater promise for growth.

       At the time of Mahoney's announcement in 1992 Monsanto's ROE was 12 percent,
well below the target.  One broad strategic implication of the new goal was for the firm to
start moving into so-called "specialty" chemicals  and out  of commodity-type chemicals.
Specialty chemicals tend to be innovative and targeted at markets where the product will
enjoy a significant competitive advantage.  Competitive advantages arise when the product
fills a new market niche or when it significantly outperforms existing, competing products.27
  24
     Return on equity is defined as the a firm's net income divided by average stockholder's equity.
  25 A high price/earnings ratio can usually be taken as evidence that market sees good growth opportunities
for the firm.

  26 Note that while ROE is a standard accounting measure, it is not a theoretically sound metric by which to
judge the desirability of alternative investments. ROE calculation does not require knowledge of cash flows
and does not involve discounting, making it a highly suspect measure of profitability.

  27 Monsanto's shift toward "life sciences" products, such as genetically engineered fertilizers, is an example
of their move toward specialty chemicals.
                                         25

-------
In contrast, commodity products tend to be high-volume, established products that are ~ by
definition — very competitively supplied.  Anti-oxidants, such as 4-ADPA derivatives, are
examples of the latter. The entire rubber chemicals business, in fact, was beginning to be
seen as a product line incompatible with the 20 percent ROE goal. Note that this shift in
strategic thinking was occurring simultaneous to the ADPA development program.

       The Rubber Chemicals Business.  The company's shifting strategic goals spelled
trouble for the Rubber Chemicals (RC) business.   International rubber chemicals markets
are highly competitive and subject to cyclical worldwide demand fluctuations. Most of
Monsanto's competitors had comparable production processes and excess capacity.  In
addition, a set of other market changes threatened the firm's strategic position. First, the
collapse of the Soviet Union resulted in a significant loss of sales in the region as Eastern
European suppliers flooded the market and created significant downward pressure on prices.
Second, Monsanto's  customers were consolidating.  In the 1980s there were 20 or more
major tire manufacturers.  By 1992,  however,  after a  wave  of failures,  mergers,  and
acquisitions 5 major tire producers were supplying the bulk of the world market.  This
consolidation allowed tire manufacturers to exercise buying power and bargain for steep
price reductions from suppliers such as Monsanto. Finally, changes in tire manufacture itself
(increased production of radial tires) were leading to long-lasting products.  Increased tire
durability meant reduced rubber demand. Rubber consumption was growing worldwide by
only 2 percent per year.

       Taken together, these strategic factors suggested that rubber chemicals was a business
where growth potential was limited, particularly in relation to other markets Monsanto might
enter.  The numbers underscored the strategic analyses. Rubber Chemicals dropped from a
business with a 16 percent ROE in  1989 to a business with an 8-fold reduction  in net income
(and a roughly 2 to 3 percent ROE) in 1992. While some of this was due to unavoidable
cyclicality, the accounting returns calculated in 1992 fell far short of corporate goals.

Capital Rationing and ADPA's  Impact on the Business Unit

       Monsanto at  the time was composed of  15 distinct business units that competed
amongst themselves for shares of a limited yearly capital budget.  Once granted, the budget
could not be exceeded without the approval of corporate headquarters. Also, any project
over a particular size had to be approved by headquarters. The capital investments necessary
to get ADPA operating  commercially placed it in this category (in  particular, plant
construction costs were large). This meant that the Rubber Chemicals business was not the
sole decision-maker.  Capital rationing and a parent business line with relatively poor
performance meant that ADPA's  financing was not assured.
                                       26

-------
       ADPA's impact on the Rubber Chemicals business was strongly positive.  The
question was, was its impact going to be positive enough to turn around the business as a
whole?  Management was looking at the following options  and projections for the RC
business.  Independent of ADPA, the business had secured internal financing to conduct a
large-scale business  reorganization.   Monsanto  had granted RC a  capital budget  to
aggressively reduce costs anywhere savings were available. The restructuring plan involved
facility closures and "debottlenecking" innovations to capture economies of scale at core
plants. Even with these efforts, and the cost and competitive advantages they would create,
the projection was for an 8 percent return on capital.28 Given the firm's new strategic targets,
this was only marginally acceptable.

       Development of ADPA would improve the Rubber Chemicals business' financial
performance. Expectations were that ADPA would add roughly 3 percentage points to the
business' return on capital.  This is significant, particularly given the dilution of its benefit
across the entire business line. Nevertheless, a 10 or 11 percent ROC remained well below
Monsanto's strategic financial targets.

What's Wrong With a 10 percent Return on Capital?

       While a 10 percent return fell short of the CEO's strategic goal, it is still natural to
ask why a firm would pass up a 10 percent return.  The short answer is that a firm can make
a 10 percent return and still lose money.  The more detailed answer requires a brief review
of financial principles.

       Before turning to that review, however, we temporarily set aside two important
issues. First, the Rubber  Chemicals unit's 10 percent ROC is not necessarily relevant to the
ADPA decision.  What is relevant are the returns specific to ADPA. Second, ROC is not a
theoretically sound measure of financial value.29  Nevertheless, ROC, while  analytically
dangerous, is not an entirely worthless measure of value. For now, we can infer ~ as did
managers at Monsanto — that a discounted cash flow analysis would produce a theoretically
sound, and qualitatively identical conclusion: the Rubber Chemicals unit was generating
positive, but lackluster,  returns.
  28
    Note that some of the figures cited in the case refer to return on capital (ROC), while others refer to return
on equity (ROE). Both are measures of investment return, though return on capital is the more comprehensive
measure since it accounts for the return on capital financed via both equity and debt.

    For reasons similar to those mentioned in footnote 26.
                                        27

-------
        T}ie Opportunity Cost of Capital. A business that makes a 10 percent return on its
capital can lose money because the capital itself has a cost. For instance, if the capital would
have earned 15 percent if used to finance a new agricultural product, then  15 percent is the
cost of capital. (In economic parlance, 15 percent is the opportunity cost of capital). Note
that a firm loses money if it takes capital away from a project that earns a 15 percent return
and puts it in a project that earns only 10 percent.

A firm will lose money if it directs capital from a project that offers a higher return to a
project that offers a lower return.  While seemingly simple, this truism has a direct corollary
that is often not understood: investing in a project with a positive rate of return can reduce
a firm's profits,

In other words, evidence that a pollution prevention investment has a positive rate of return
is not the same as evidence that it is an economically desirable project.

        This economic reasoning can also shed light on CEO  Mahoney's  20 percent ROC
target.  Given new  technological and market opportunities opening to Monsanto, the
direction of capital toward Rubber Chemicals had a high opportunity cost.  In fact, this cost
may have been so high that investment in assets promising a 10 percent return would have
reduced the value of the firm.   This was particularly true given the financial risks presented
by the Rubber Chemicals business, an issue to which we now turn.

       Risk, Return, and the  Cost of Capital. The opportunity cost of capital is a function
of more than the returns offered by alternative investments.  It is also a function of those
investments' risk.

        Given a choice between a risky investment and a safe one, an investor will always
prefer the safer of the two.   The implication is that, in order to acquire capital from an
investor, the riskier  firm will have to promise a higher return than the safer firm.30  In turn,
this means that the opportunity cost of an investor's capital is higher for riskier firms. Thus,
a firm's cost of capital is related to the way in which capital markets assess its risk. These
ideas  are the basis of understanding the so-called  capital asset pricing  model (CAPM).
CAPM says that an  asset's expected risk premium varies in  direct proportion to an index of
  30 This explains why so-called prime lending rates, with which most consumers are familiar, are always well
below the corporate cost of capital (hurdle rate). To compensate for the greater risk relative to treasury bills,
the market provides an average risk premium well above the return provided by safe treasury bills.
                                         28

-------
risk, called beta.31 Because riskier firms must offer a higher return, capital is more expensive
for them to acquire.

       Risk and the Rubber Chemicals Business.  Not all risks affect capital costs.  For
instance, because  of the  ability to diversify, investors can significantly reduce risks by
holding a portfolio of investments whose uncertain price movements "cancel out" on
average. A risky investment can have a "low beta," and in turn relatively low capital costs,
as long as the risks it presents are diversifiable.  Only non-diversifiable risks affect capital
costs.

       Non-diversifiable risks are a function of several factors. Perhaps the most important
factor is the sensitivity of a firm's earnings to the economy's overall business cycle.  It is
noteworthy that the Rubber Chemicals business is highly cyclical, and so would be expected
to have a high beta. Also, a project's operating leverage — the proportion of its costs that are
fixed and that therefore must be borne regardless  of whether the  asset is ultimately
productive or idle — influences the project's risk. All else equal, projects with higher fixed
costs will have higher betas.32 On this score, too, Rubber Chemicals is likely to have a high
beta. The fixed costs  associated with chemicals manufacture tend to imply high project-
specific betas.  This would also hold true for the ADPA investment itself.

       Because of the  non-diversifiable risks associated with the RC business, and ADPA
specifically, the cost of capital for this business could be higher than 10 percent, perhaps
significantly so.  High risk, low return businesses  are not desirable targets for capital
investment. For these reasons it is not surprising that some within Monsanto were resisting
any continued investment in the RC business.

Disentangling ADPA from the Rubber Chemicals Business

       Strictly speaking, the firm's concern with returns in the RC business should not have
been relevant to the ADPA investment decision.  An inviolable principle of financial project
evaluation is that a new investment should be evaluated "incrementally," not on the basis of
its impact on average returns across a larger business. Financial theory holds that, when
  31
     Statistically speaking, beta is the ratio of (1) the covariance between an asset's return and the return of
a broader portfolio, and (2) the variance of the broader portfolio. Typically, the broad portfolio is a diversified
portfolio of publicly traded stocks. Beta therefore measures the sensitivity of an asset's value to changes in
the market generally.

  32 For more detail on how to estimate aproject's beta see Foster (1978).
                                         29

-------
evaluating a new capital investment, only the new, appropriately discounted, cash inflows
and outflows created by the project are relevant. Taking this view, ADPA was a much better
investment than indicated by calculations such as "ADPA will improve the RC business'
ROC by 3 percentage points."  In fact, a preliminary estimate suggested that, on its own,
ADPA promised a 45 percent return on capital, a return well above the firm's strategic target.
Given  that projects should be evaluated incrementally, and given the high ROC  estimate,
why didn't the firm simply move ahead with ADPA as a stand-alone project?

       Monsanto analysts sought to view ADPA independently, but in the end "couldn't
divorce" ADPA from the RC business. To understand why, it is necessary to highlight a key
technical interdependence associated with the 4-ADPA process. This technical relationship,
in turn, had financial and accounting implications that tied the ADPA decision to the RC
business and other integrated Monsanto businesses.

       4-ADPA and Chlorobenzenes. The old 4-ADPA production process required large
quantities of a product called PNCB (paranitrochlorobenzene). This  product, along with a
co-product, ONCB (orthonitrochlorobenzene), was produced by another Monsanto division.
The innovative ADPA process eliminated the bulk of Monsanto's PNCB needs and would
severely limit the availability of ONCB. In fact, this is  a  primary source of ADPA's
economic benefit. Process steps and raw inputs used to make  chlorobenzenes are eliminated
by ADPA.  This change, however, meant that the financial impact of ADPA could not be
isolated. Costs associated with chlorobenzenes had to be considered. These  costs can be
separated into two categories. First, ADPA created cash outflows by reducing efficiencies
in chlorobenzene production and requiring plant decommissioning expenditures. Second,
ADPA raised accounting issues within Monsanto  related to the recovery of fixed costs
associated with now-redundant chlorobenzene units.

       Negative Cash Flows  Created by  the Switch  to ADPA.   While reduced
chlorobenzenes was a benefit of ADPA, there were also some off-setting costs associated
with reduced chlorobenzenes production. First, closure of one or more chlorobenzene units
was a possibility.   In  many ways  this was considered a desirable  outcome (the
chlorobenzenes business, like Rubber Chemicals, was relatively lackluster). Nevertheless,
there were costs associated with closure.  Some of these costs were tangible, such as the cost
of decontaminating and disposing of redundant, non-salvageable capital equipment.  Others
were less tangible, such as the impact on the workforce of plant closures. Second, Monsanto
still required PNCB and ONCB for other products, though in limited quantities.  This meant
that the elimination of all the firm's PNCB plants was not possible. The elimination  of
chlorobenzenes from 4-ADPA production meant that these plants would be significantly
under-utilized, and thus be less efficient to operate. Because plants were optimized for pre-
ADPA production volumes, ADPA would have the effect of increasing operating costs at the
                                       30

-------
 PNCB plants remaining on-line. These costs, because they were cash outflows and the direct
 result of a shift to ADPA, were relevant to the financial analysis of ADPA.

       Accounting Charges Associated with ADPA. Looming even larger were a set of large
 fixed costs associated with the now-obsolescent chlorobenzene facilities. With PNCB no
 longer being used by Rubber Chemicals, the chlorobenzenes business would have a much
 harder time recovering the fixed costs associated with its production. As a result, financial
 projections  for the ADPA project and the RC business as a whole included "charges"
 corresponding to these unrecovered fixed costs.  This had a clear, negative impact on the
 ADPA project's economics.

       From the standpoint of financial theory, these costs should not have been assigned
 to ADPA or Rubber Chemicals. Unrecovered fixed costs from the chlorobenzenes business
 were, technically speaking, sunk costs and therefore should have been irrelevant.33 The cost
 of building the chlorobenzene plants was a cash outflow that occurred many years before the
 ADPA decision was made.  Whether or not ADPA went forward, Monsanto had already
 borne this cost.

       It is  common to confuse sunk costs and cash flows.  One reason is that accounting
 procedures take a  fixed cost and "depreciate," or spread, it over a period of years. But
 depreciation does  not mean that the firm is paying a fraction of a  fixed cost in yearly
 installments. Rather, depreciation is  a technique required by the tax system to calculate a
 firm's yearly profits (and thus its tax liability). While for tax purposes the method spreads
 a cost over a number of years, there is not a yearly cash outflow. The actual cash outflow
 typically occurs earlier, at the time the capital is installed ~ for instance, when contractors
 and equipment suppliers are paid.

       Also, large fixed costs create complicated issues for  diversified firms  such  as
Monsanto. In order to compare the value and performance of individual business units, firms
will typically  make  those units into  distinct "profit centers."  Profit centers allow each
business unit (such as Rubber Chemicals) to be evaluated on its own terms. This leads to
better investment decisions and, with performance monitoring, allows the firm to create
managerial incentives tied to an individual unit's successes and failures.  An issue arises,
however, when one  internal business requires an input from another internal business:
namely, how is that input to be priced? While not purchased on the open market, the input
must have a "price" that can be assigned to the appropriate profit center. The simple answer
  33 .
   ' The so-called "sunk cost fallacy" is a common and time-worn error in financial analysis. For examples
see Brealey and Meyers (1991), pp. 96-98.
                                       31

-------
is that the internal price should be equal to the cost of producing the input. This becomes
complicated, however, when the cost involves fixed costs that must be  shared between
businesses.

       Rubber Chemicals was being "charged" just such an internal price for the PNCB used
to make 4-ADPA. This is a completely sound financial practice, and one that is necessary
for firms using distinct profit centers as an internal accounting strategy. With ADPA,
Rubber Chemicals no longer needed PNCB. This threatened the chlorobenzene business'
ability to recover its fixed costs via Rubber Chemicals charges. The accounting solution was
to  charge Rubber Chemicals obsolescence costs (the unrecovered chlorobenzene costs).
Again, this is a sound financial practice, if it is used simply to assign costs for internal
accounting purposes.   What was unsound was the assignment of obsolescence costs to
ADPA during the project's financial evaluation. The assignment was inappropriate because
the unrecovered, fixed chlorobenzene costs were sunk costs. As cash flows, they had been
paid out years earlier. The confusion was natural enough. After all, the Rubber Chemicals
business had been seeing chlorobenzene charges as annual cash outflows.  From the larger
corporate perspective, though, the unrecovered chlorobenzene costs should have been
identified as sunk and thus irrelevant to the ADPA decision.

       Failure to appropriately distinguish between financial measures such as cashflows,
       accounting charges, and sunk costs can bias analysis of new investments.

       These financial evaluation issues ultimately did not hinder  the development of
ADPA.  The innovation's benefits were so obviously positive that development went
forward.  But the case provides a lesson in the complexities and challenges that confront
financial evaluation. Financial analysis techniques are an area where many firms continue
to innovate and improve quality. In this regard, it is instructive to note that current internal
guidelines at Monsanto  stress the importance  of incremental analysis to sound capital
budgeting evaluations.  A similar change has occurred with regard to discounted cash flow
techniques.  As we have seen, in the early 90s Monsanto used non-discounted cashflow
benchmarks (e.g.,  return on capital) to compare projects.  The firm's current capital
appropriation procedures require discounted cash flow measures of expected profitability.

ADPA's Commercial Development

       ADPA was a technology with significant economic value.  Unfortunately, the product
it produced was embedded in an under-performing business.  The strategic solution, and
what ultimately guaranteed ADPA's development, was Monsanto's divestiture of the Rubber
Chemicals business.  In 1995, Monsanto formed a joint venture, Flexsys America, with Akzo
                                       32

-------
Nobel. The venture provided a desirable solution to several of the strategic and financial
issues raised by ADPA and the rubber chemicals market.

       Under the firms' agreement, Monsanto would transfer to Flexsys the bulk of its
rubber chemicals capital base, including a number of plants worldwide, as well as rights to
the proprietary ADPA technology. Akzo Nobel would transfer several of its own rubber
chemicals products and businesses to Flexsys. Ownership of the joint venture was evenly
divided between the two firms  and the resulting  business was  able  to finance the
development of an ADPA production facility in Belgium.

       The  joint venture promised several benefits.  It permitted consolidation in the
European rubber chemicals market. In particular, the firms would be able  to capture scale
economies in production and staffing.  Also, the joint venture implied  significantly greater
market share. This promised a competitive advantage that could be  used to counter tire
manufacturers' increased buying power in the rubber chemicals market.

       While Monsanto had to share its new technology,  the joint venture allowed them to
shed the RC business' under-performing capital assets and get another firm to underwrite the
ADPA's commercial development costs.  ADPA's implementation ultimately hinged on a
major business restructuring, brought on by worldwide market changes and shifting strategic
goals.

Environmental Accounting

       ADPA's entanglement with complex production and strategic issues should not
obscure the fact that a primary driver for its development  was pollution prevention.
Pollution prevention motivated the R&D effort which spawned the new process chemistry.
Given this, and given the significant environmental benefits associated with ADPA, how was
the value of this improvement expressed in the firm's financial decision-making process?

       The environmental benefits were not translated into financial terms that had a direct
impact on the decision  analysis. There are several reasons for this.   First, the financial
analysis of all costs and benefits — not just environmental costs and benefits — was relatively
rudimentary. As indicated earlier, year-by-year cash flows were only estimated. A detailed
line-item cost and benefit analysis was not conducted.  While the firm failed to quantitatively
account for financial benefits arising from changed environmental conditions, it also failed
to quantitatively account for many other benefits and  costs.  Second, it could be argued that
detailed financial analysis of environmental changes was unnecessary because the waste
reductions were so obviously large that there was no need to estimate their precise financial
value.
                                        33

-------
       The goal of environmental exist accounting is to ensure that environmental costs (and
 savings from reduced costs) are given weight in decision-making equal to the weight given
 to  non-environmental  costs and benefits.   We should  ask, then,  whether  ADPA's
 environment-related financial benefits - though not quantified - got equal qualitative weight
 in the firm's decision-making. There is evidence that ADPA environmental benefits were
 prominently valued in the firm's decision-making. A good guide to this is the prominence
 of environmental considerations in business summaries presented to top management.
 Internal documents show that waste reduction was listed as a key driver in favor of ADPA
 in every summary of the investment's pros and cons  presented to  financial staff.  In a
 "Corporate Finance Staff Review" ADPA's environmental benefits are presented on equal
 footing with financial and strategic considerations.  Or consider a decision brief presented
 to CEO Mahoney that included a small list of key considerations, two of which were related
 to the project's environmental benefits.  These summaries invariably included statements
 such as "reduces waste by 95%." Environmental problems associated with chlorobenzene
 production were also typically listed as reasons to get out of that business.34  While state of
 the art risk analysis and financial  estimation of these environmental benefits was not in
 evidence during the ADPA decision, there is no evidence that environmental benefits were
 being given insufficient weight hi the business'  decision calculus.
   34
     These problems included the production of hydrochloric acid salts. While not a regulated substance,
elimination of this waste stream was nevertheless seen as having a significant (if unqualified) value.
                                        34

-------
DnPont
The Product

       The DuPont case relates to a product called the "DuCare" photochemical processing
system. The DuCare system is a package of four integrated products designed for sale to
customers in the graphic arts (printing and publishing) industry. The industry, in the process
of developing 1.5 billion square feet of silver halide photographic film annually, generates
a huge amount of photochemical waste.  The DuCare system was designed to reduce
photochemical consumption and the industry's pressing disposal needs.  In lieu of traditional
fixer and developer chemistries, DuCare uses proprietary process chemistries that allow for
recycling.  The four integrated products that make up the DuCare system include (1) a
proprietary, recyclable "developer," (2) a recyclable "fixer," previously commercialized by
DuPont, (3) a transportation system that collects and returns the developer and fixer to a
DuPont processing facility for recycling, and (4) technical assistance in the choice and
installation of washwater treatment technologies. Note that the chemicals are not recyclable
on site. Instead, the chemicals require transport to a central facility where the recycling
chemistry takes place, followed by re-distribution to the graphic arts customer.  The goal of
the system is a "zero  effluent" photochemical process.35  The target customer base is
composed  of  medium-  and  large-scale  commercial  printers  and  publishers  with
environmental compliance, stewardship, and cost concerns.

The Pollution Prevention Opportunity

       The  environmental benefits of the DuCare system are, by design,  significant.
Traditional methods for dealing with photochemical waste include direct release to the drain
for subsequent treatment at a POTW (publicly owned treatment works), transport of wastes
for off-site TSDF disposal, or illegal dumping.  DuCare, by recycling the photochemicals,
eliminates releases to the environment, whether those releases are destined for the drain, a
treatment works, or a disposal facility.

       A variety of wastes are eliminated by a recyclable chemical process. With respect
to photographic developer, the  standard process creates an  environmentally problematic
chemical oxygen demand (COD).  A typical developer has a high COD of roughly 100,000
ppm.  As a point of reference, the EPA limit is a COD of 2,000 ppm. Again, spent developer
is either is hauled away for disposal at a licensed toxic substance disposal facility, is dumped
  35
    While the product must be transported off-site, it is technically a form of "in-process" recycling.
                                        35

-------
illegally, or is sent legally to a POTW where treatment charges may be levied. The DuCare
developer, by being fully recyclable, eliminates all of these releases.

       There are significant environmental gains associated with the fixer and washwater
treatment, as well.  The standard photographic fixer, if untreated, contains 2,000 to 6,000
ppm of silver (EPA limit,  .7 ppm), 40,000 ppm of ammonia (900),  180,000 ppm total
sulfates (5,000), and has a COD of 120,000. Most photoprocessing labs use some method
to reduce silver concentrations, but all of the other undesirable effluents generally remain
untreated. Again, because it is totally recyclable, the DuCare fixer completely eliminates
these releases. The DuCare washwater treatments reduce freshwater consumption, which is
significant in photochemical processing.  These kinds of benefits arise each time a graphic
arts customer employs the product. Calculated on a base of 500 customers, DuPont estimates
that the DuCare system results, annually, in a 10 ton reduction in silver emissions and a
375,000 ton reduction in other chemical wastes.36

       From a private financial perspective, DuPont saw a commercial opportunity in its
ability to sell this kind of pollution prevention.  This is in contrast to the two cases we have
previously analyzed.  In the previous  cases, the analysis related to decisions regarding a
firm's own investment in pollution prevention. The DuPont case is somewhat different. The
DuPont case features financial and marketing analysis relating to a pollution prevention
technology that it wishes to sell to other firms. To a great extent, then, the case's focus will
be on the demand of DuPont's customers for pollution prevention.

       Customer demand for pollution prevention was a primary motivator for DuPont's
development of the product.  The DuCare system was envisioned as a way to reduce
environmental  compliance costs for its film and photochemical customers. While being
associated with environmental leadership is mentioned in company documents as a desirable
aspect of the product, the primary motivation was financial.  DuPont expected to make
money by selling pollution prevention to its customers.  The market opportunity became
possible via the reality (and perception) of increasingly stringent environmental regulation.
37
  36 DuPont estimates that, industry-wide, 30 million gallons of used fixer and developer are created annually.
On the assumption that each square meter of processed film creates 800 ml of waste fixer and developer, this
annual effluent contains approximately 1,000 tons of hydroquinone, 1,000 tons of sodium sulfite, 2,000 tons
of ammonia, and 75 tons of silver. Currently, the vast majority of this waste either is released to POTWs or
is dumped illegally.

  37 DuCare strategy documents highlighted changing patterns and stringency of regulation. "Public concern
about the environment has led to more regulations and increasing enforcement. As a result, photochemical
effluents are coming under greater scrutiny and more stringent control across North America."
                                         36

-------
As product  planning proposals spelled out  clearly,  "customers want to  minimize
environmental risk and liability and want help in managing these issues."  By eliminating
emissions, DuCare would help its customers' regulatory compliance issues disappear. There
was the possibility that the DuCare system might be viewed by regulators as  a best available
control technology status. ^Moreover,  full recyclability meant that customers who used third-
party disposal would eliminate any "cradle to grave" liability exposures associated with that
transaction.

       The regulatory and legal environment in which graphic arts photo-processors exist
was expected to give rise to a demand for pollution prevention. This demand could be
satisfied via DuPont's technology, service, and transportation system, presumably at some
profit to DuPont.  Also, there was  a generally accepted belief among managers that an
environmental processing technology  would lead, not only to increased photochemical sales,
but to increased film sales, as well. This was a significant financial driver for DuPont since
film sales create the bulk of its graphic arts revenues and profits.38

DuCare Today

       The DuCare system was introduced commercially by DuPont in 1994. Since then,
the product has been successful, when viewed from a technical  perspective.   From a
chemistry and product design standpoint, all elements of the system have performed as
projected. Unfortunately, the product has failed, by a significant margin,  to live up to its
initial financial promise.  Development-stage projections were quite promising.  A 1993
financial analysis predicted that the product would have a 10-year net present value of $2.78
million, not including film sales attributed to customer use of DuCare. Film sales generated
by DuCare were estimated to have  an additional $6.5 million 10-year NPV.  Currently,
however, the product has failed to turn any profit.  Excluding the uncertain value of
stimulated film sales, the product has to date been unable to earn  revenues sufficient to
recover operating and startup costs.

       The most direct explanation for this failure to meet expectations is that consumer
demand for the product has been much weaker than predicted. A 1992 business plan offered
a "conservative" estimate that DuCare would lead to a 10  percent ~ and continuously
increasing — market share in the graphic arts film and photochemicals business. Today, that
market share is less than 5 percent. Out of  an estimated universe of more than 16,000
potential customers, DuCare is currently used by fewer than 600.
   38
      This synergy was quantitatively estimated in firm analyses.  Each gallon of recycled developer was
expected to generate demand for 50 to 100 square feet of DuPont film.
                                        37

-------
       The DuPont graphic arts business unit -- the business unit that developed  and
commercialized DuCare — is. being sold to Agfa, a competitor in the graphic arts business.
The sale comes on the heels of relatively poor financial performance from the graphic arts
business unit generally.  DuPont's inability to motivate significant sales of the DuCare
system contributed to these financial difficulties. We now turn to the question of why
demand for the DuCare product fell so far short of expectations.

Why Has Demand for the DuCare System Been Relatively Weak?

       DuCare is a pollution prevention technology embedded in a photo-processing system.
DuPont's customers,  while potentially drawn  to  pollution prevention,  are  primarily
purchasing a photo-processing system.  The photo-processing  market itself is quite
competitive.  DuPont's  direct competitors include Kodak, Agfa,  Anitec, Fuji, and 3M.
Thus, a direct, but incomplete, explanation for DuCare's financial under-performance is that
other firms have out-competed DuPont.  To understand  why this may be,  note that a
customer is essentially choosing a process technology with two primary features: price and
environmental performance. DuCare has failed to sell up to expectations because it is at the
high end of the price spectrum and because customers (apparently) do not feel that  its
environmental characteristics are sufficiently valuable to outweigh the price premium.  At
this point it is useful to turn to a more detailed analysis of DuCare's costs and environmental
benefits, relative to other options available to DuPont's customers. We will compare DuCare
to (1) DuPont's existing (and more "standard") photochemical process and (2) a competing,
photoprocessing technology with pollution prevention features.

       A non-environmental cost comparison. First, consider the non-environmental costs
associated with the alternatives. These include up-front capital, chemical input, chemical
processing, and transport costs.

       DuCare vs.  the standard process. Excluding environmental considerations, the
standard photochemical process is cheap, relative to DuCare. The chemicals employed are
cheaper to produce and more competitively supplied. The recyclability of the DuCare
chemicals means that there is less of a need to  purchase "fresh" chemicals, but the
transportation and chemical recycling costs mean that even recycled batches of the chemicals
are more expensive than DuPont's standard chemicals. For example, the standard developer
costs $1.79 per gallon.  The DuCare developer is more than twice as expensive, costing
$4.65 per gallon. This is a single up-front cost differential, however, since it relates only to
the cost of the initial batch of developer. Subsequent, recycled batches cost $1.38 per
gallon. Does this mean that the DuCare developer is cheaper in the long run? No, since the
$1.38 cost does not include the cost of transporting the developer as part of the recycling
process.  Transportation costs add an additional $.81 per gallon.
                                        38

-------
        As for the recyclable fixer, it is more expensive than standard fixer, but is also of
 higher concentration. The greater concentration implies a lower replenishment rate, so that
 customers ultimately need to purchase less fixer. So despite its higher price per gallon, the
 recyclable fixer's effective cost is roughly equivalent to the costs of a non-recyclable fixer.
 Again, though, transportation adds further  to the overall cost.   Because fixer  has  a
 "hazardous" regulatory classification, its transportation costs are even higher than they are
 for developer.  With a hazardous classification, licensed transport and storage is required.
 This translates into fixer transportation costs of $1.42 per gallon, on average.  (A  set of
 additional problems associated with fixer's hazardous classification is discussed below).

        Up-front capital costs associated with the standard DuPont and DuCare systems are
 comparable.

        DuCare vs. a competing environmental process. A competing technology, called On
 Line Recirculating Electrolysis (ORE) allows for effluent reductions and reduces the fixer
 replenishment rate.  From a non-environmental standpoint, the ORE technology requires a
 much higher up-front capital cost ($10,000 versus $3,000) than does the DuCare  system.
 However, it has lower on-going chemical costs and, because it is not a recycling technology,
 does not have the costs associated with chemical transportation to a recycling facility.
 Excluding environmental  considerations, the ORE technology  is a cheaper long-run
 alternative to DuCare. And because of its desirable impact on fixer replenishment, its  long-
 run cost may be even less than the cost of the more standard photochemical process.

       Note that this cost analysis highlights a fact with significant competitive implications.
 Quite simply, unless compliance costs are considered to be a relevant concern, the DuCare
 system  is more expensive than other options available to DuPont's customers.

       The environmental comparison. From an  environmental perspective, the existing
 DuPont process and the ORE process cannot compete with DuCare. The full recyclability
 of the DuCare chemicals means that effluent wastes are essentially eliminated.  As noted
 earlier,  photochemical processing creates significant silver, COD, ammonia, and sulfates
 emissions. The ORE process allows for on-site silver removal. The ORE system does not
 address the non-silver effluent streams, however.

       With the ORE and standard method, therefore, photo shops can dispose of non-silver
waste by sending it to the drain or by shipping the waste to a third-party site for disposal.
The latter is the environmentally preferable disposal method. This "hauling" and disposal
option is costly, however.  In fact, if a photo shop is going to haul waste for disposal, these
hauling costs imply a net process cost greater than that associated with the DuCare system.
                                        39

-------
                              Standard process      ORE system
DuCare
 Operating cost (0/sq.ft.
 film)
            without hauling

               with hauling

 Silver to drain (ppm)
            without hauling

 COD to drain (ppm)
            without hauling

 Initial capital cost ($)
7.6
26.6
130
5200
2,900
6.0
23.4
5
2700
10,000
8.4
8.9
<1
100
3,000
                                      Table 1
       Table 1 presents a simplified summary of the characteristics of DuCare, relative to
the other two methods.39 It is likely that a customer would use the kind of data contained in
this table when making the decision of which photo-chemical process to use. The table
highlights the fact that none .of the processes is cheapest in all circumstances. In particular,
note how the desirability of the DuCare system is a function of whether or not the customer
hauls its waste for off-site disposal.  If the customer hauls waste, DuCare is by far the
cheapest  method  (8.9 cents per square foot of film  developed), in  addition to being
environmentally superior. However, if the customer does not haul its waste, DuCare is the
most expensive option (8.4 cents).

       Based on this analysis, it would be natural to conclude that demand for the DuCare
P2 technology is a direct function of whether or not customers are hauling their waste for
disposal, instead of releasing effluents directly to the drain.  The gamble DuPont took with
DuCare hinged on whether or not hauling waste would be a de facto regulatory requirement
  39 The data is based on DuPont financial analysis. The DuCare product always requires transport. The
DuCare "without hauling" option, the less than 1 ppm silver release, and the 100 COD release to the drain,
arise from wash water, not fixer or developer, disposal.
                                         40

-------
due to stricter effluent standards and greater enforcement. According to one document, "in
areas with strict regulations where hauling waste is becoming the norm, the Zero Effluent
offering will have a significant cost advantage." The fact that demand for DuCare has not
been as  strong as  envisioned may be  explained by relatively  lax enforcement  of
photochemical waste regulations.

Regulatory Pressure and the Market for P2

       From  the  beginning, the project's financial  and strategic  analyses identified
regulatory pressure as the primary driver of the market for DuCare.  Much of DuPont's
optimistic financial and marketing analyses was predicated on the assumption that regulatory
compliance and standards would continuously tighten and affect larger and larger numbers
of graphic arts facilities.  Because of the perceived trend in regulatory stringency, the firm
felt that "the financial advantage of competitive offerings is already gone in some areas and
is expected to be short-lived in many more."  As part of its analysis, DuCare financial
projections and  business plans  included an "environmental pressure  map" of the United
States. This map ranked different areas (down to the zip-code level) in terms of regulatory
stringency — stringency being measured by allowable silver concentrations and the perceived
likelihood of enforcement Three categories were differentiated: "strict," "transitioning," and
"lax."40  Customer concentrations were then laid on top of this map to create an overall
estimate of the number of potential customers in stringent or transitioning areas.  These firms
were DuPont's target customer group.

       The importance of regulatory pressure is further highlighted by the degree to which
lax regulatory enforcement was viewed by project managers as an unlikely risk, but one of
the key assumptions on which marketing projections were based.  As one document, labeled
"Key Business Risks and Assumptions" put it, there was  a risk that "customers may be
unwilling to pay for [DuCare] services in environmentally  lax or transitioning areas."

       Existing effluent standards can act as a powerful motivator for pollution prevention
       by creating markets for technologies that can address firms' compliance issues.  It
       is important to emphasize, however, that standards must be monitored and. enforced.
       if they are to have the maximum impact.
   40
     "Strict" areas were defined as those in which there was an enforced silver standard below 1 part per
million. A "lax" area was one in which the standard was greater than 5 ppm or one in which standards were
"not enforced" at all.
                                        41

-------
       It is  difficult to definitively establish that insufficiently aggressive effluent
monitoring and enforcement is the root cause of DuCare's difficulties. The financial analysis
presented  above, however, points to  enforcement issues  as at least  a partial cause of
DuPont's marketing problems.

       It is not entirely surprising that monitoring and enforcement would be problematic.
Photochemical drain discharge occurs in relatively small amounts and by  numerous,
geographically diffuse, and shallow-pocketed firms. Monitoring difficulties are particularly
significant hi jurisdictions that face budgetary and technical enforcement constraints.41

       Moreover, marketing  surveys  conducted by DuPont lend weight to the overall
conclusion that the threat of regulation is the key driver for DuCare's customers. The firm
surveyed all DuCare customers in 1995, asking them to indicate the importance of a range
of factors that contributed  to their decision to adopt the DuCare pollution  prevention
technology.  The following is the percent of those responding who ranked the factor as
extremely or very important (only the top six factors are reproduced below):

       Factors considered central to adoption                    % saying yes

       The ability to meet future regulatory requirements            96
       The ability to meet existing regulatory requirements          94
       The ability to reduce chemistry consumption                 72
       Elimination of the need to measure and mix chemistry         66
       Ability to market environmental leadership to
              customers and employees                            61
       The automated collection and distribution system             61

Clearly, regulation-related concerns are the most prominent motivator. The survey also
revealed that 90 percent of DuCare's customers described their firms as existing in an
"extremely, very, or somewhat strict" regulatory climate. At the very least, this analysis
suggests that perceptions of regulatory stringency are central to the firms' demands for the
DuCare product.
  41
   A common means of monitoring is to monitor "downstream," or aggregated effluent currents. Given the
dilution that occurs by the time downstream measurements can be taken, however, it can be very difficult to
establish responsibility or standards violations unless the release is particularly large.
                                        42

-------
A Regulatory Barrier

       DuCare can help customers achieve regulatory compliance and reduce expected
liability costs, but only if regulation and liability are perceived to be problems worthy of
consideration by customers. In this way, the above discussion highlights the sensitivity of
demand for DuCare to regulatory enforcement. An appropriate conclusion to draw is that
stronger regulation is good for pollution prevention.

       Interestingly, the DuCare case also highlights the way in which regulation can be bad
for pollution prevention. In particular, the spent fixer's regulatory classification raises the
costs of  providing  and using DuCare.   In  this instance, regulatory interventions are
inhibiting the diffusion  of pollution prevention.

       Used fixer, even if part of a recycling-based system, is given a "spent material"
RCRA classification.  An unfortunate consequence of this rule is that, simply by using the
product, DuCare customers become hazardous waste generators.  According to several
people interviewed for the case,  regulatory burdens associated with this rule create a
powerful motivation to simply discharge used fixer to the  drain and POTW. The RCRA
classification issue is the largest source of DuCare customer complaints. Its costs are difficult
to quantify but are related to several factors.  From a customer's standpoint, the spent fixer
distribution system requires them to administer special handling and storage, labeling,
training, and reporting procedures.42 Many small printers have never had experience with
this sort of regulatory program.  For firms that generate other hazardous waste streams, the
spent fixer classification — and use of DuCare-- may "bump" them from small-quantity to
large-quantity generator status. This would imply a set of additional regulatory burdens
associated with that type of classification.  Again, it is difficult to quantify the impact of
these requirements on demand for DuCare. It is safe to say, however, that the hazardous
classification has not helped DuPont in its efforts to market the product.

       The classification also increases the costs of providing the recycling system. As
noted earlier, the "reverse distribution" system that sends the fixer back for recycling is a
major cost component. The hazardous classification means that the developer and fixer must
be shipped separately.  The inability to consolidate shipments  increases costs, since there are
scale economies associated with the transport of loads to the central processing facilities.
The licensed transport required for the fixer is approximately twice as  expensive as the
  42 For example, recycled shipments must be "manifested." This involves an EPA number for shipment and
documentation of goods to be shipped, quantities, transporters, and destination.  And requirements differ
widely across states, requiring state-specific compliance expertise on the part of DuPont's customers.
                                         43

-------
transport used for the spent developer (spent developer has a less  onerous "corrosive"
Department of Transportation classification).

       In some cases, regulatory rules can raise the costs of supplying and using pollution
       prevention technologies. This can have the unintended consequence of inhibiting the
       diffusion of technologies with desirable environmental characteristics.

       The spent fixer classification is a concrete example of a regulatory barrier to pollution
prevention.43 By raising the DuCare product's direct cost (via transport  and storage charges)
and creating administrative burdens for customers, the  rule may be creating a negative
environmental impact.  Drain disposal is the predominate alternative to DuCare.  It  is
therefore reasonable to assume that the rule's burdens have created some shift toward drain
disposal, a decidedly less desirable means of dealing with photochemical waste.
  43 DuPont has raised the fixer classification issue with the EPA, which is currently considering a change in
the classification of silver-bearing waste. In the past, the official position has been that no special exemption
is available and that, in any event, precious metal reclamation exemptions may apply to DuCare materials.
There is a significant lack of clarity in that rule's interpretation, however. Moreover, many states do not have
precious metal exemptions.
                                          44

-------
4.  Information  and  the  Financial  Evaluation  of  Pollution  Prevention
Opportunities

       The case studies provide a window into firms' concrete strategic, technical, and
financial thinking. In particular, they provide insight into the ways in which firms collect,
process, and act on information when making investment decisions. We now return to some
of the broader questions that motivated the study.  Is information relating to environment-
related financial benefits appropriately reflected in corporate decision-making?  Are the firms
coming to financially sound conclusions?  Are there straightforward financial benchmarks
that can be relied on to indicate the profitability of pollution prevention? Based on what was
learned in the cases, we offer some tentative conclusions.

Are environment-related financial  benefits being captured appropriately by the
decision-making process?

       One of the primary challenges to pollution prevention is the need  to define and
quantify the benefits of such investments. An emerging literature emphasizes the desirability
of methods such as environmental cost accounting as a means to improve corporate decision-
making. With the identification and quantification of environment-related financial benefits,
firms can be expected to make better private, and environmental, decisions.44 For instance,
environmental accounting can highlight the way in which changes in a production process
reduce future environmental compliance costs.  This reveals  a benefit to investment from a
process change, a benefit that may not otherwise have been captured in a capital budgeting
decision. The quality of environmental accounting is of clear importance, and. not least to
firms themselves. Are financial benefits being captured adequately?

       As we evaluate firms' accounting of environment-related financial benefits and costs,
it is important to distinguish between two types of questions. First, to what extent are
financial benefits and costs quantified?  Second, are environment-related financial benefits
and costs, even if not quantified, being given sufficient weight relative to non-environmental
benefits and costs?  Note that the first question deals with the detail and numerical
sophistication of quantitative estimation techniques — the way in which the firm determines
the bottom-line impact of activities that affect the environment.  The second question deals
with the impact of accounting techniques on the firm's  decisions.  Failure to accurately
quantify benefits and costs could bias investment decisions  against pollution prevention.
  44 See White, Becker, and Goldstein (1992) and White, et al. (1995).
                                        45

-------
The quantification of environment-related financial benefits
       Consider first the issue of quantification.  The financial analyses associated with the
above cases show relatively little economic quantification of environment-related financial
benefits and costs. In almost none of the documentation reviewed were dollar values
attached to savings from reduced emissions or liabilities.  (There are a couple of exceptions
worth noting. The first is the dollar value of savings associated with avoided incinerator
upgrade costs in the Dow case.  The second is DuPont's analysis of benefits associated with
not having to haul and treat spent photographic fixer and developer wastes.45) In fact, one
of the cases revealed an example of management spelling out its desire to explicitly avoid
the use of certain quantified environmental benefits during economic evaluation. An internal
Dow document states that "savings from enhanced environmental protection and avoidance
of liability will not be considered in economic evaluation.  These issues will be a factor hi
the leadership  decision-making  process..."  In other words, describe the enhanced
environmental protection, but don't give us a dollar estimate of its value.

       How is this lack (or explicit avoidance) of environmental accounting data to be
interpreted?  First, it should be pointed out that, while economic values are not quantified,
there is extensive technical quantification of environmental benefits (e.g., pounds of a
pollutant eliminated annually). In all of the cases,  for instance, emissions reductions are
analyzed and quantified in a variety of ways. The only step that is missing is the translation
of these technical environmental benefits into financial benefits.  Why is this step not taken?
The best explanation is that it is simply too difficult to arrive at economic values with any
precision.  When a firm is estimating conventional costs, such as the cost of a new  piece of
capital equipment, something as simple and available as the market price of the item can be
used.  There is no analogous list of prices, or costs, that can be  used to translate  reduced
environmental emissions into a dollar value.  Methodologies chosen to do  so  may be
somewhat ad hoc, and thus of questionable accuracy.

       Methods for environment-related financial benefit estimation are being improved.
For instance, depending on the type of financial benefit being estimated, historical data can
be used as a guide to avoided future costs (the benefit).  As technologies, consumer tastes,
and regulatory standards change, however, the  ability to quantify these benefits and costs
accurately  becomes more  difficult.   It may  be reasonable for  upper management to
discourage the use of quantification techniques that are untested and aimed at the estimation
of values that are so inherently uncertain.
  45 TTiemore pertinent question in the DuPont case is whether or not DuPont's customers go through a similar
calculation.  While DuCare is marketed in a way that conveys compliance-related savings, it is not clear that
compliance is considered a relevant issue by many of its potential customers.
                                         46

-------
       The evidence suggests that better forms of environmental accounting are needed.
However, it also suggests that there are significant challenges to the collection and analysis
of this type of data.  For instance, when dealing with new products and processes, where can
data on  their environmental risks  be found?  To illuminate this problem,  consider the
distinction between cost estimation and cost accounting. Historical cost accounting data
(i.e., data that is certain) can be used for cost estimation, but only if past costs are a good
guide  to future costs.  This may not always be so.  Historical, actuarial  environmental
accounting data is not useful if it provides data on environmental risks, technologies, and
legal situations that firms are not likely .to encounter in the future. For instance, a firm's
expected future liability costs should probably not  be  estimated by looking at its past
Superfund liability costs. Because of Superfund, firms dispose of wastes very differently
than they did 20 and 30 years ago. Because of its highly uncertain technical and legal nature,
environmental cost estimation  may  inherently be more speculative than we, or firms
themselves, would hope.

The effect of uncertain financial benefits on decision-making
       Given the lack of quantified financial benefits, do the cases suggest that potential
environmental  improvements are given inadequate weight by corporate decision-makers?
The answer is no.  While un-quantified, environmental benefits are given  significant
qualitative value in the decision-making process.   Evidence for qualitative weighting
includes the inclusion of environmental benefits as key  "drivers" in the^ecision-making
process.  Environmental benefits,  such as physical data on quantities of/emissions reduced,
are routinely featured in summary documents presented to upper management at the time of
decision-making. The "paper trail"  (agendas,  strategic analyses, and  decision-making
summaries) followed to re-construct  these cases   are permeated with a  qualitative
understanding of environmental benefits.  The cases suggest, therefore, that non-quantified
environmental benefits do not necessarily imply an inadequate weighting of environmental
benefits in the decision-making process. Instead, lack of quantification may simply indicate
the inherent difficulty of establishing precise financial  values.  In light of this, it also
deserves mention that many types of accounting data (i.e., not just environmental accounting
data) are  often incomplete and surprisingly imprecise. Thus, evidence of poor  environmental
accounting data and procedures can be viewed as a symptom of poor accounting techniques
generally, rather than as evidence of a specific environmental accounting problem.46
    There is a justifiable concern that environmental benefits may not be captured adequately by accounting
procedures based on short time horizons. However, in the cases (Dow and DuPont) where yearly cash flows
were estimated, the time horizon used was ten years.  (Current corporate guidelines at Monsanto require
evaluation over a 10 year horizon). Particularly given the effects of discounting, a 10 year horizon is
methodologically sound and should capture the lion's share of net present environmental benefits.
                                         47

-------
Are firms missing win-win pollution prevention opportunities?

        Some observers believe that companies fail to pursue their own economic self-
interest when it comes to pollution prevention. For instance, Porter (1995, 132) claims that
companies exaggerate the risk of environmental investments, use inappropriate rate of return
hurdles, and thus "leave ten-dollar bills on the ground."  This type  of assertion, while
thought-provoking, is difficult to prove or refute without evidence related to actual corporate
investment decisions. Even when an investment is explored in detail, as in the NRDC study
of the same Dow LaPorte investment described in this paper (Greer and van Loben Sels,
1997), conclusions  about an investment's economic desirability are often  made without
adequate analysis of business and financial considerations.47

        The case studies in this paper were motivated in large part by the desire to better
understand the corporate rationale for rejecting, or delaying, identifiable pollution prevention
opportunities.  As the cases show, basic concepts from business and financial theory suggest
mat the firms' investment decisions were financially rational. This is contrary to the view
that firms suffer from a myopic inability to appreciate cost-saving P2 investments. Instead,
significant unresolved technical difficulties, uncertain market conditions, and, in some cases,
regulatory  barriers  or  insufficient  emissions enforcement,  rendered the investments
financially unattractive. In many cases, the mystery of why firms  do not pursue P2
opportunities can be resolved by simply having a deeper understanding of the costs, benefits,
and risks associated with those investments.

        This conclusion implies nothing about the social desirability of the firms' decisions.
Reasonable persons can ~ and do — differ regarding how much pollution prevention is the
right amount of pollution prevention. But it does imply that there may be fewer high-return
P2  opportunities than many believe.  Those who favor mandated, command and control-
style, regulations may wish to claim that many high-return, win-win opportunities exist,  but
that firms ignore those opportunities.  After all,  if this were true, command and  control
regulations could be viewed as forcing firms to do what is in their own economic self-interest
  47 This paper's description of the La Porte investment decision owes a great deal to the NRDC's excellent
technical study of pollution prevention opportunities at the plant. It disagrees with the study's conclusions
regarding the financial desirability of TOX retirement, however. Dow's failure to approve the investment is
taken as evidence that "cost savings are not enough to convince industry to adopt prevention actions" (p. 418).
This conclusion is based on the authors'  belief that TOX retirement would reduce costs for Dow.  But
conclusions about cost savings require business and financial analysis that is as detailed as NRDC's technical
analysis. When detailed financial analysis is brought to bear on the question of cost savings, those savings are
far from certain.
                                          48

-------
anyway.  This line of thinking should be viewed with skepticism.  The investments analyzed
here were by no means clear-cut financial winners. The cases suggest that firms are quite
capable of identifying the actions that are in their greatest financial self-interest.

Information barriers and the search for clear financial benchmarks of P2 profitability

       The cases challenge the belief that organizational barriers are to blame for missed or
delayed P2 opportunities.  Nevertheless, it should also be clear that firms face significant
informational problems when they evaluate new investment opportunities. Managers never
have perfect information regarding the costs and benefits of a new investment.  In fact,
imperfect information explains a great deal about the way in which firms analyze and make
investments. It is important, however,  to distinguish between a firm's imperfect methods for
dealing with imperfect information and evidence of organizational failures.

       The term "organization failure" connotes the existence of a correctable management
strategy, accounting procedure, or financial methodology. For instance, if the benefits of an
environmental investment were analyzed only over a 3-year horizon, this could easily be
labeled an organizational failure.  The failure to account for benefits beyond three years
could  easily be corrected by a longer-horizon  investment analysis. And better, more
profitable decisions would be expected. Similarly, if financial managers rarely spoke with
environmental managers  or  infrequently integrated regulatory expertise  into business
analysis, this could be easily, and profitably, corrected. The cases, however, exhibit little in
the way of these correctable types of failure.  Instead, the cases  depict managers struggling
with much more formidable challenges to investment decision-making ~ challenges that are
pervasive and not limited to the analysis of environmental investments.

       Consider the concept of a "hurdle rate" for new investments.  Most firms define a rate
of return that new projects must exceed before capital is directed toward the investment.  In
general, firms will  not make investments that fall short of the hurdle rate, even if the
investments have a positive rate of return. This can be a source of frustration to advocates
of pollution prevention, who see a positive rate of return as evidence of profitability. A
positive rate of return seems to be  a clear benchmark.  When firms ignore that benchmark
and focus on some higher hurdle rate it is natural to suspect the firm's "decision rule." But
is a hurdle rate decision rule a correctable organizational failure? The answer is no.  Hurdle
rates and the rationing of capital serve an important, inescapable corporate function.  They
are means by which firms account for the risks of investment and inherent imperfection of
information at their disposal.
                                         49

-------
 The rate of return
       In order to explore these concepts in more  detail, consider a hypothetical P2
 investment opportunity that has been estimated to have a 30 percent rate of return.  How can
 we explain why a firm would not make an investment that offers such an apparently positive
 return on investment?

       In a capital budgeting context, the "internal rate of return" (ERR) on a proposed
 project is a function of the timing and size of "cash flows" associated with the project. Cash
 flows include the initial cost of a project (the outlay)  and its subsequent inflows (such as
 sales revenues). While rate of return is a concept that seems intuitive, it is actually quite
 subtle.  Consider the technical definition of ERR: a project's internal rate of return is the
 discount rate at which the project's net present value is zero.  While the technical definition
 is somewhat obscure, for simplicity, it is possible to think of rate of return as a measure that
 accounts for a project's benefits and costs, year-by-year.

       The first point to make about IRR calculations is that in the capital budgeting stage
 rates of return are always estimates, and thus are inescapably uncertain. An IRR estimate is
 only as good as the analysis on which it is based. Techniques such as environmental cost
 accounting are methods to improve the accuracy of these estimates.  Environmental cost
 accounting allows for a more complete accounting of the cash flows that form the basis of
 the IRR calculation. A problem with rate of return calculations may be that they fail to
 incorporate "soft" (harder to quantify) costs and benefits. If this is true, a 30 percent rate of
 return estimate may be "adjusted" qualitatively by managers. For instance, if a project has
 a calculated rate of return of 30 percent, but will result in employee layoffs, the cost of which
 has not been quantified, managers should view the 30 percent figure as being too high.
 Alternatively, if the project analysis  does not include environmental cost savings, managers
 would, appropriately, view the 30 percent figure as too low.

       Accounting techniques must be evaluated in order to determine whether reported
       benchmark figures (such as rate of return) are viewed by management insiders as
       complete and unbiased Managers are likely to better understand the ways in which
       their own analyses are biased.  If so,  benchmark figures must be interpreted with
       care, particularly by outside analysts.

       Assuming  the IRR is an unbiased, accurate estimate, the financially sound IRR
 investment rule is as follows: proceed with the investment  if the IRR exceeds the cost of
 capital. Technically speaking, this rule ensures that the investment has a positive Net Present
Value, a measure of profitability.  Projects are desirable (profit-maximizing) only if they
have  positive NPVs.  Thus, the IRR figure is by itself not a guide to an investment's
desirability.  It is the comparison of ERR and cost of capital  that is relevant.
                                        50

-------
Risk and the cost of capital
       What is meant by the "cost of capital?" First, note that the cost of capital has little to
do with what we normally think of as a "cost." In particular, it is distinct from the cash
outlays necessary to buy equipment or change a production process. These conventional
costs are, in financial parlance, "negative cash flows." The cost of capital is not a cash flow.
Instead, a project's cost of capital is defined as the "opportunity cost of using the capital for
the project versus using it for some other equivalent project." In other words, if a project
requires a $100 cash outlay, the cost of capital is not the $100.  The cost of capital is the cost
of not spending the $100 on something else.

       Returning to the definition, the cost of capital is the opportunity cost of using the
capital for this project versus using  it for some  other equivalent projects.   What are
equivalent projects? Equivalent projects are those that pose  equivalent risks.   The
relationship between risk and the cost of capital is central to the analysis of capital budgeting
decisions.  When someone loans or invests their money they are concerned with both the
expected return on and the risk associated with the loan or investment.  Investors have
varying "tastes" for risk and return.  Some prefer safer investments.  Those willing to accept
risk can do so, and because they take on these risks, command a higher expected return.

       When a firm seeks money for a risky project it must raise the capital from investors
who are attracted to the level of risk and return presented by the project. But note that these
investors  could just as easily invest their money in  other firms'  risky projects.  The
opportunity cost of investing $100 in the project is thus the cost of giving up the opportunity
to invest $100 in other projects with similar risk profiles. What is the "opportunity" that is
being given up?  The opportunity is the ability to earn the rate of return associated with the
other projects. If a 30 percent return can be earned on  other investments, a firm needs to
show investors that their risk-equivalent project can yield a return of at least 30 percent.

        Determining the  cost of capital therefore requires an  understanding of other
opportunities available in the market. Financial tools such  as the Capital Asset Pricing Model
(CAPM)  account  for the importance of risk  and are designed  to  value  investment
opportunities. Capital cost estimation requires knowledge of the broader market's "risk free
interest rate" and "market risk premium." These terms, respectively, relate to the returns
offered by a perfectly safe investment  and a diversified  stock or bond portfolio.  Then,  the
firm must estimate its  equity and debt "betas."  Roughly, these betas measure  the
 contribution  of an investment in the firm to the riskiness of a diversified portfolio. With
these estimates a firm's cost of capital can be estimated. The technical, mathematical  nature
 of these concepts should not obscure the fact that the process of estimating them is as much
 an art-form as it is a science.
                                          51

-------
       Rate of return is relevant only as it compares  to a project's cost of capital.
       Moreover, the cost of capital is not typically easy to measure, since it is intimately
       related to project risk. Thus, the implication of a particular rate of return figure for
       decision-making requires detailed knowledge of factors contributing to risk.  No
       single rate of return  "hurdle" can  be used as  a benchmark for judging an
       investment's profitability.

       Finally, it should be noted that a firm's cost of capital will not in general be the same
as the cost of capital for a specific project. Because the cost of capital is a function of risk,
capital costs will  differ in different divisions,  for different product lines, and across
individual projects.  If the project in question is riskier than the firm's business generally, the
cost of capital will be higher — because riskier investments demand a higher return. Ideally,
then,  it is desirable to estimate the equity and debt betas associated with investments that are
equivalent to the contemplated project.  This usually  involves the estimation of betas
associated with other firms' investments. The difficulty in determining investments that are
"risk-equivalent" is one of the things that makes the task subjective.

Capital rationing
       Now assume that a firm has calculated a project's cost of capital at 25 percent. If the
IRR  is 30 percent, should  the firm make the investment? In  general,  yes, since these
numbers indicate a positive net present value (the rate of return exceeds the opportunity cost
of capital).  In practice, however,  businesses commonly depart from a pure "positive net
present value" decision rule. In other words,  firms do  not generally move forward with
projects simply because they have positive NPVs.  Instead, firms often set limits  on the
capital available to individual business units.  This places a ceiling on funds available for
new investment and forces managers to prioritize across projects, all of which may have
positive NPVs. This financial management technique is termed  "capital rationing" and is
used commonly in the private sector.

       Capital rationing is in evidence in the Monsanto and Dow cases. The P2 projects had
positive rates of return, rates that may in fact have exceeded the firms'  costs of capital.
Nevertheless, the supply of investment capital to the business decision-making units was
limited by corporate headquarters. Thus, the capital constraint can be viewed as a culprit in
the failure of the firms to move forward with the investments. After all, if the businesses had
no such constraint any investment with a positive  NPV would  presumably be financed.
Given this, is capital rationing an organizational barrier  to pollution prevention? In other
words, is the rationing  of  capital an irrational, correctable corporate decision-making
procedure?
                                         52

-------
       To answer these questions, it is necessary to explore firms' rationale for limiting the
availability of capital to their business units. The principal rationale is that capital rationing
is necessary for internal financial control. In this view, rationing counters the tendency of
managers to overstate the benefits of investment opportunities with which they are involved.
In general, it is very difficult to align the personal incentives of managers with the incentives
of the firm as a whole. For instance, compensation and prestige are invariably related to the
scope of projects under a manager's control.  This creates a tendency to propose and seek
acceptance of a large number of investment projects.  One way to seek acceptance for
projects is to make capital budgeting estimates that are over-optimistic. That is, managers
may be led to bias their forecasts of cash flows associated with a new investment (e.g.,  over-
state expected benefits or under-state expected costs).  Again, this emphasizes the inherently
uncertain, and subjective, nature of financial data.  Capital rationing, therefore, is a means
to correct largely unavoidable problems associated with imperfect information, managerial
monitoring, and investment incentives.48 It should not be viewed as an easily correctable
organizational failure.

       When capital is rationed, investments are not judged on the basis of whether the rate
of return exceeds the cost of capital (the positive NPV rule).  Instead, projects are typically
ranked, with capital invested in those promising the highest net return. In practice, this can
mean that the most rational investments need not be those that promise the highest rates of
return or net present value.   Instead, the most desirable projects are those that provide the
highest NPV per dollar  invested.49

       The implication  is that capital rationing leads firms to prioritize their investments.
While this may mean that certain P2 opportunities are passed over, it does not in general
mean that environmental investments are disadvantaged.  The Dow La Porte investment is
illustrative.  One reason the TOX elimination project has not moved forward is  that the
project has failed to meet the polyurethane business' current hurdle rate. The hurdle rate was
high — roughly 86 percent.  The hurdle rate was this high, however, because an alternative
use of the business' funds promised an 86 percent return. Given capital rationing, money
used at La Porte would have taken away from this other project. In effect, the "bar was
raised" on the La Porte investment because of the need to prioritize expenditures and the
  48 For analyses that explore the theoretical justification for capital rationing see Holmstrom and Costa (1986)
and Antle and Eppen (1985). They show how the private concerns of managers, combined with private
information, can create managerial incentives to over-invest. Capital rationing is shown to be an effective
corporate strategy to counter these incentives.

   49 See Brealey and Meyers (1991) who give examples of the way in which investment rules under capital
rationing can violate the idealized NPV rule.
                                          53

-------
existence of higher-priority investments.50 Also, it is worthy of note that the higher-priority
investment was also more environmentally beneficial than the La Porte P2 investment would
have been. Source reductions associated with the rival investment exceeded reductions at
La Porte by an order of magnitude.  Thus, prioritized capital budgeting should not be viewed
as a barrier to pollution prevention. In fact, financially prioritized investment is also likely
to lead to prioritized environmental innovation.
  50 The rationing issue was addressed by internal corporate decision-making documents in the following way:
"The polyurethane business is global and makes capital environment decisions based on global priorities. The
cost and return of the TOX elimination project was not as favorable as other projects the business is funding.
These other projects include as much as a hundred million dollars in capital and two new source reduction
technologies which will eliminate 30-60 million pounds per year of material from incineration by increasing
the yield of processes in the polyurethane business."
                                            54

-------
5. Conclusion: Pollution Prevention and Public Policy

       The cases presented in this analysis were explored in order to shed light on the
organizational and economic issues that shape pollution prevention decision-making. For
those concerned about environmental quality, it is natural to be frustrated with decisions that
reject or delay investments that could improve a corporation's environmental performance.
Much of that frustration may be alleviated, however, via a  better understanding of the
strategic and financial factors that affect the profitability of pollution prevention investments.

       This analysis' conclusions should not be taken as either a defense or condemnation
of the firms' environmental performance. The "right" level of pollution prevention to be
undertaken by the corporate sector is a question left to a different study (though it is worth
emphasizing that regulations,  and the avoidance of regulatory costs, were in all the cases a
"driver" that motivated the firms' search for pollution prevention).  Still, without a detailed
accounting of social benefits and costs, little can be said about whether more or less stringent
regulation was appropriate in these cases. Instead, the cases say much more about the way
in which firms are regulated.

       The results of this analysis can be viewed largely as a defense of the soundness with
which managers weighed the private benefits, costs, and risks of the pollution prevention
investments they were evaluating. Instead of revealing evidence of corporate organizational
barriers or myopic decision-making, the cases demonstrate a set of complex, but ultimately
prosaic motivations for the decisions that were made.  Appreciation of those motivations is
important because it can help guide public- and private-sector efforts to improve corporate
pollution prevention performance.

       The findings here run counter to the perception that firms are somehow failing to
pursue win-win opportunities. Instead, failure to pursue P2 is usually best explained by a
project's lack of expected profitability. Surely some profitable P2 opportunities have gone
undetected by the private sector.  But once unearthed, firms have both the motive and ability
to evaluate profit opportunities. Convincing firms of the profitability of investments they are
uniquely capable of evaluating themselves is likely to be a relatively unconstructive approach
to P2 promotion.  Instead,  a more  fruitful approach is to focus  on  barriers  to  P2's
profitability.

       What policy changes are likely to enhance P2's profitability? First, the cases reveal
regulatory barriers of varying significance. The desire to experiment with P2 innovation is
often thwarted by rigid media- and technology-specific regulations.  The rigidity of many
regulations is  understandable  given  the  difficulties  of environmental  enforcement.
Nevertheless, efforts to promote regulatory flexibility and innovations should be embraced
                                        55

-------
as a means to foster the corporate sector's ability to develop environmental innovations. The
DuPont case featured a regulatory barrier associated with a material classification issue.
While there are sound reasons for the material classification system in general, removal of
that barrier would be a desirable example of "seeing the regulatory forest for the trees." In
specific cases, rules act at cross purposes with the environmental goal. Flexibility is the only
way to avoid that kind of problem.  Of course, the DuPont case also highlighted a way in
which lax regulatory enforcement can weaken the demand for P2 technologies.

       Second, performance-based (as opposed to technology-forcing) regulation is likely
to be a better way to promote private sector P2 innovations.51 P2 increasingly calls for firms
to engage in the redesign of complex products and processes in  ever-changing  product
markets.  Performance-based regulations, which allow greater latitude for technological
experimentation and longer time-horizons for compliance, allow firms to meet targets in the
largest variety of ways.52 In contrast, existing regulations feature substantial regulatory
influence  over the technologies used  by firms. Not only are specific technologies often
mandated, but technical constraints also arise because emission standards are applied to
individual substances rather than broader categories of effluent. Because of this, limits on
the output of a single substance can significantly constrain the design (or redesign) of a
production process.53  Moreover, because of an emphasis on specific abatement procedures
for specific effluent streams, firms must continually re-permit as their production processes
   51 Instead of judging environmental compliance on the basis of specific technological inputs or narrowly-
defined emissions standards, performance-based regulation relies on more holistic measures of a facility's
environmental performance.  For instance, compliance with aggregate limits (on a  larger "bundle"  of
chemicals), rather than chemical-specific limits, is consistent with a performance-based approach.  The EPA's
"Project XL" ~ a voluntary industry-regulator initiative to promote innovative forms of environmental
regulation ~ is currently fostering experimentation with performance-based permitting.

   52 Care must be taken not to confuse "flexibility" with a lack of regulatory stringency.  Flexible permitting,
at the aggregate level, can be very stringent.  But flexible permitting allows firms to meet even stringent
aggregate targets in the way they best see fit.
   Performance-based regulation is not without limitations of its own. Monitoring and enforcement issues, in
particular, loom large. The uniformity (inflexibility) of standard command and control regulations is a virtue,
since it is  easier to monitor technology or emissions standards that are fixed and common to many firms.
However, given the unique characteristics of most firms, the constraints imposed by uniform standards should
be viewed as a potentially significant barrier to P2 innovation.

  53 Emission standards may not explicitly dictate a technology choice. However, they often carry an implicit
incentive to employ a standard technology. This is because standards are usually developed based upon the
emission characteristics of  specific technologies. Firms can minimize their likelihood of being found in
violation of standards  by  employing the  technologies on which the standards were based.   Innovative
approaches run a higher risk of generating permit violations, or triggering permitting delays.
                                            56

-------
change.  This re-permitting is a costly and time-consuming exercise in and of itself ~
particularly for firms whose production processes must change frequently. Performance-
based environmental permitting should be explored as a means to lower these barriers and
constraints.

       Flexible, performance-based regulation has another important consequence: namely,
it enhances the private sector's demand for improved environmental accounting information.
Rigid regulations do a particularly poor job of fostering the private sector's demand for, and
development of, better environmental accounting information and methods. After all, end-
of-pipe, single-media, and technology-forcing regulations leave firms with little reason to
innovate,  and therefore even less  reason to  collect information that would reveal
environment-driven financial opportunities. Better information helps firms only if they have
the flexibility to act on —and benefit from— better information. Regulatory flexibility, by
expanding the technological options  open to firms, increases the value of information
relating to those options. In the end, regulation that allows for a wide variety of innovative
solutions is likely to be the best way to induce firms to invest in  better environmental
information and decision-making.

         The  analysis  of financial evaluation  procedures has highlighted significant
information barriers faced by firms.  This underscores the continued importance of improved
environmental cost accounting methods to better estimate  environment-related financial
benefits.  Improved data collection, estimation, and evaluation techniques can only improve
corporate decision-making.  The important, and open, question for future research is: what
forms of environment-related information are likely to be most valuable to the private sector?
This study has suggested that firms can be expected to do a relatively good job of evaluating
the environmental and financial characteristics of P2 opportunities, once those opportunities
are identified.  Perhaps the greatest challenge for firms, however, is the initial identification
of those opportunities. The technical identification of P2 opportunities may be well served
by greater efforts at basic R&D and firm-specific "materials accounting."54  Mandated
accounting requirements are of questionable value, given the idiosyncratic needs of specific
firms and facilities.  And confidential business information issues undermine the practicality
of mandatory and publicly-disclosed P2 planning. However, government promotion of state
of the art accounting practices, including materials accounting, is likely to concretely benefit
firms that are increasingly concerned with environment-related costs and opportunities.
   54 Materials accounting denotes efforts to track the physical flow of materials into, through, and out of a
 given facility.
                                         57

-------

-------
                                    References

Antle, Rick and Gary Eppen. "Capital Rationing and Organizational Slack in Capital
       Budgeting," Management Science, 31:2, 1985, pp. 163-174.

Brealey, Richard and Stewart Meyers, Principles of Corporate Finance, (New York: McGraw-
       Hill), 1991.

Commoner, Barry, "Pollution Prevention: Putting Comparative Risk Assessment in Its Place," in
       Worst Things First? The Debate over Risk-based National Environmental Priorities
       Adam Finkel and Dominic Golding, editors (Washington, D.C.: Resources for the
       Future), 1994.

Dixit, A. and R. Pindyck, Investment Under Uncertainty, (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
       Press), 1994.

Environmental Protection Agency, Amoco - U.S. EPA Pollution Prevention Project: Yorktown,
       Virginia, Executive Summary, (U.S. Environmental Protection Agency: Washington,
       DC) December, 1991 (revised May, 1992).

	} Pollution Prevention 1997: A National Progress Report, EPA 742-R-97-00, Office of
       Pollution Prevention and Toxics, (United States Environmental Protection Agency:
       Washington DC), June, 1997.

Foster, George, Financial Statement Analysis, 2d. edition, Prentiss Hall: Englewood Cliffs, NJ,
       1978.

Greer, Linda, and Christopher van Loben Sels, "When Pollution Prevention Meets the Bottom
       Line," 31 Environmental Science and Technology, 1997, 418-422.

Freeman, Harry, Teresa Harten, Johnny Springer, Paul Randall, Mary Ann Curran, and Kenneth
       Stone, "Industrial Pollution Prevention: A Critical Review," Journal of the Air and
       Waste Management Association 42,1992, 618-656.

Holmstron, Bengt and Joan Ricart I Costa, "Managerial Incentives and Capital Management,"
       Quarterly Journal of Economics, November 1986, 835-860.

Natan, Thomas, Catherine Miller, Bonnie Scarborough, and Warren Muir, "Evaluating the
       Effectiveness of Pollution Prevention Planning in New Jersey: A Program-Based
       Evaluation," Hampshire Research Associates, Alexandria, VA, 1996.

Pelley, Janet, "Environmental R&D Shifts to Pollution Prevention," Environmental Science and
       Technology News, March 1997.
                                          58

-------
Porter, Michael E., "Green and Competitive: Ending the Stalemate," Harvard Business Review
       Sept.-Oct, 1995,pl20-134.

Sarokin, David et. al., Cutting Chemical Wastes, (Inform, New York), 1985.

White, Allen, Monica Becker, and James Goldstein, Total Cost Assessment: Accelerating
       Industrial Pollution Prevention through Innovative Project Financial Analysis, Office of
       Pollution Prevention and Toxics, EPA/74 l/R-92/002, May 1992.

	} Deborah Savage, Julia Brady, Dmitri Cavander, and Lori Lach, Environmental Cost
       Accounting for Capital Budgeting: A Benchmark Survey of Management Accountants,
       Office of Pollution Prevention and Toxics, EPA/742/R-95/005, September, 1995.
                                         59

-------