United States
Environmental Protection
Agency
Office of Water
Washington, D.C.
EPA 800-R-94-002
March 1994
           PRESIDENT CLINTON'S
         CLEAN WATER INITIATIVE:

       Analysis of Benefits and Costs
                                        Recycled/Recyclable
                                        Printed with Soy/Canola Ink on paper that
                                        contains at least 50% recycled fiber

-------
                            ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

This document was prepared with the assistance of the following federal agencies:

                           Office of Environmental Policy
                           Council of Economic Advisers
                          Office of Management and Budget
                             National Economic Council
                          Environmental Protection Agency
                             Department ^of Agriculture
                             Department of Commerce
                               Department of Defense
                               Department of Energy
                               Department of Interior
Technical assistance was provided by:

Eastern Research Group, Inc.
Cadmus, Inc.

-------
                                  Table of Contents
 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
                                                                               ES-1
 1     Introduction	
 2     Approach	
 3     Nonpoint Source Controls	
       3.1   Private Sources
       3.2   Municipalities
       3.3   State Water Programs
       3.4   Federal Agencies
       3.5   Benefits
 4     Storm Water	
       4.1   Private Sources
       4.2   Municipalities
       4.3   State Water Programs
       4.4   Federal Agencies
       4.5   Benefits
5      Combine Sewer Overflows	
       5.1    Private Sources
       5.2    Municipalities
       5.3    State Water Programs
       5.4    Federal Agencies
       5.5    Benefits
6      Toxics Controls	
       6.1    Private Sources
       6.2    Municipalities
       6.3    State Water Programs
      6.4    Federal Agencies
      6.5    Benefits
7     Comprehensive Watershed Management
      7.1    Private Sources
      7.2    Municipalities
      7.3    State Water Programs
      7.4    Federal Agencies
      7.5    Benefits
I     Permit Discharge Fee	
      8.1    Private Sources
      8.2    Municipalities
      8.3    State Water Programs
      8.4    Federal Agencies
  .1
  .2
  .5
 14
 22
 27
30
34

-------
      Groundwater Protection
                                                                                 36
      9.1   Private Sources
      9.2   Municipalities
      9.3   State Water Programs
      9.4   Federal Agencies
      9.5   Benefits
10    Pollution Prevention Plans  	
      10.1  Private Sources
      10.2  Municipalities
      10.3   State Water Programs
      10.4   Federal Agencies
11    Domestic Sewage Exclusion/Pretreatment .  . .
      11.1   Private Sources
      11.2   Municipalities
       11.3   State Water Programs
       11.4   Federal Agencies
12    Permits/Enforcement/Water Quality Standards
       12.1   Private Sources
       12.2  Municipalities
       12.3  State Water Programs
       12.4  Federal Agencies
 13    State Revolving Fund/Construction Grants . .
       13.1  Private Sources
       13.2  Municipalities
       13.3   State Water Programs
       13.4  Federal Agencies
 14    Monitoring	
       14.1  Private Sources
       14.2  Municipalities
       14.3  State Water Programs
        14.4  Federal Agencies
 15    Abandoned Mines  	
        15.1  Private Sources
        15.2  Municipalities
        15.3  State Water Programs
        15.4  Federal Agencies
        15.5  Benefits
  16    Market Incentives - Effluent Trading	
        16.1  Point Source - Nonpoint Source
        16.2  Point Source - Point Source
        16.3   Nonpoint Source - Nonpoint Source
        16.4   Pretreatment
38
39
 40
 41
 42
  43
  46
                                            11

-------
17    Aggregate Benefit Estimates	
      17.1   Introduction
      17.2   Limitations
      17.3   Methodology and Assumptions
      17.4   Summary of Benefits Results
48
Appendices

Appendix A:  Nonpoint Source Case Studies
Appendix B:  Storm and Surface Water Utility, Bellvue, Washington
Appendix C:  Benefits of Toxic Reduction Case Studies
Appendix D:  Detailed Aggregate Benefit Anatysis
                                         111

-------
                                   List of Tables

Table
Number     Title

ES-1         Summary of Current and Planned Spending Under the Existing CWA
ES-2         Summary of Incremental Costs of the Initiative
ES-3         Summary of  Cost  Savings/Costs  Avoided of the Initiative Compared With
             Stringent Interpretation of Existing CWA Requirements
ES-4         Summary of Current and Potential Spending Under Stringent Interpretation of
             CWA
ES-5         Summary of Aggregate Annualized Costs From Control of Urban Sources Under
             the Initiative and Pending Spending (CSOs, Storm Water, Toxics)
ES-6         Summary of Aggregate Annualized Benefits From Control of Urban Sources
             Under the Initiative and Pending Spending (CSOs, Storm Water, Toxics)
1            Classification of Nonpoint Source Sectors
2            Impacts of the Initiative's Nonpoint Source Control Requirements on  Private
             Sources
3            Descriptive Statistics of the Coastal and Noncoastal Zone
4            Impact of the Initiative on Federal Agencies
5            Use Support Status of Assessed River Miles and Miles Impacted in Part by
             Selected Sources
6            Use Support Status of Assessed River Miles  and Miles Impacted Solely by
             Selected Sources
7            Use Support Status of Assessed Lake Acres and Acres Impacted in Part by
             Selected Sources
8            Use Support Status of Assessed Lake Acres and Acres  Impacted Solely by
             Selected Sources
9            Likelihood That Full Implementation of Management Measures  will Improve
             Water Quality in Threatened  and Impaired Rivers
10           Likelihood That Full Implementation of Management Practices  will Improve
             Water Quality in Threatened  and Impaired Lakes
11           Summary of Likelihood That Full Implementation of NFS Management Measures
             Will Measurably Improve Water Quality - Rivers
12           Summary of Likelihood That Full Implementation of NFS Management Measures
             Will Measurably Improve National Water Quality - Rivers
13           Summary of Likelihood That Full Implementation of NFS Management Measures
             Will Measurably Improve Water Quality - Lakes
14           Summary of Likelihood That Full Implementation of NFS Management Measures
             Will Measurably Improve National Water Quality - Lakes
15           Summary of CSO Costs and Benefits of Various Control Options
16           Impacts of the Initiative's Domestic Sewage Exclusion Provision on Private
             Sources
                                       -iv-

-------
17           Summary of Aggregate Annualized Costs From Control of Urban Sources Under
             the Initiative and Pending Spending (CSOs, Storm Water, Toxics)
18           Summary of Aggregate Annualized Benefits From Control of Urban Sources
             Under the Initiative and Pending Spending (CSOs, Storm Water, Toxics)
19           Summary of Current and Planned Spending Under the Existing CWA
20           Summary of Incremental Costs of the Initiative
21           Summary of  Cost Savings/Costs Avoided of the Initiative Compared With
             Stringent Interpretation of Existing CWA Requirements
22           Summary of Current and Potential Spending Under Stringent Interpretations of
             CWA
                                           -v-

-------
                                   List of Figures
Figure
Number

ES-1
ES-2
ES-3
ES-4
ES-5
ES-6

1
2
 Title

 Annual
 Annual
 Annual
 Annual
 Annual
 Annual
Cost of Major Provisions
Cost of Major Provisions: Private Sources
Cost of Major Provisions: Municipalities
Cost of Major Provisions: Agriculture
Cost of Major Provisions: States
Cost of Major Provisions: Federal Agencies
Nonpoint Source Management Measures Applied in Benefits Analysis
Costs and Benefits of CSO Controls
                                       -vi-

-------
                                 List of Appendices

Appendix A Nonpoint Source Case Studies
Appendix B Bellvue Washington Storm Water Case Study
Appendix C Benefits of Toxic Reduction Case Studies
Appendix D Detailed Aggregate Benefits Analysis
                                           -vii-

-------

-------
                                  Executive Summary

Introduction

       This report summarizes  the costs and  benefits of provisions  contained in President
Clinton's  Clean Water Initiative.  As noted in Executive Orders  12866  and 12893,  such
comparisons are necessary because resources committed to implement the Initiative can be used
for alternative productive purposes. Therefore, the opportunity costs of these resources should
be compared with the economic benefits.  Such comparisons should be used to help fashion
policies that offer the largest possible net benefits.

       In addition to estimated costs and benefits, many factors  need to be taken into account
in  supporting an environmental initiative.   These  include  large uncertainties and  gaps in
estimating benefits and costs, the  distribution of benefits and costs among segments of the
American people, and support  of the public  for environmental controls.   Regarding  these
matters, the Administration believes that it is appropriate to be on the side of environmental
caution because of the large uncertainty about the effectiveness of proposed controls, and about
the benefits and costs generally.  The Administration also recognizes the continuing support for
the  Clean Water Act (CWA)  both in Congress and by the general public.   Finally, the
Administration believes that cleaner water is especially important because it provides benefits
that are distributed broadly among all Americans,  irrespective of income levels or ethnic
background.

        The Initiative will require  incremental expenditures of $5 to $9.6 billion per  year.
However, compared with the costs  of a stringent interpretation of the current law, the Initiative
will yield potential savings  (or avoid future costs) of $29 to $33.8 billion.

Approach

        Scope.  This report  presents the costs of the Initiative, measures of physical benefits of
the Initiative, and estimates of  the costs and monetized benefits of provisions of the Initiative
applicable to urban areas only.

        Costs are reported in two different ways. First, they are provided by sector: (1) private
 sources (i.e.,  industry, commercial and private individuals),  (2) agriculture (farmers), (3)
 municipalities  (including  operators  of public wastewater  treatment  facilities),  (4)  state
 governments, through their water programs, and (5) federal agencies. It is recognized that some
 of the effects of the Initiative are  transfers rather than costs.  Second, costs are provided for
 each major provision of the Initiative.  For comparison with monetized benefits in urban areas,
 incremental costs are also reported for three general provisions:  storm water Phase I and II,
 combined sewer overflow controls, and toxics.

        Benefits of the Initiative  are  reported in physical  terms,  such as stream  miles of
 improvements.  For urban areas only, benefits are reported in monetized terms; we account for


                                           ES-1

-------
 a large variety  of  benefit categories,  the most  important being  recreational fishing  and
 swimming.

       Estimates of the Initiative's impact were developed by the U.S. Environmental Protection
 Agency (EPA) Office of Water in consultation with EPA's Office of Policy, Planning,  and
 Evaluation and other federal agencies, including the U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA),
 U.S. Department of the Interior (DOT), U.S. Department of Commerce (DOC)  - National
 Oceanographic and Atmospheric Administration (NO A A), U.S. Department of Defense (DOD),
 and U.S. Department of Energy (DOE), as well as with the White House Office of Management
 and Budget (OMB), Council of Economic Advisers (CEA),  and National Economic Council
 (NEC).

       Baseline.  Some provisions of the 1987 Clean Water Act Amendments have not yet been
 implemented.  Some provisions of the  Initiative will impose new responsibilities and costs
 beyond those called for in the 1987 Amendments.  Others scale back obligations under the
 Amendments and will save the private sector, municipalities, and the  federal government
 billions of dollars while not compromising environmental quality.  Therefore, it is legitimate to
 view the baseline from which costs of the Initiative are estimated in two ways: as increments
 above current and pending spending or as reductions in costs from stringent interpretations of
 the 1987 CWA.  The stringent interpretations reflect the reading of the law proposed by various
 outside groups but do not represent EPA's best interpretation of the law. However, while EPA
 believes that these interpretations are stringent and inflexible, they could potentially be adopted
 by a court in litigation challenging EPA's interpretation.   This report carefully distinguishes
 estimates from these two baselines.

       Consistency in Benefit and Cost Estimation.  To assure that urban area benefits and
 costs are comparable, a number of steps were taken.  The  costs and benefits are presented in
 annualized 1993  dollars.  Benefits are discounted using three different discount rates (zero,
 three, and seven percent), and assuming that they are fully in place in 15 years. This procedure
 is necessary to account for the fact that benefits or costs experienced later in time are worth less
 than those experienced sooner.  The nature of environmental risks is that it will take time to
 fully attain many of the projected water quality improvements and economic benefits.  Costs are
 annualized at seven percent.

       Uncertainties in Estimating Costs. To account for the uncertainty inherent in estimating
 costs for various  provisions, we have  used ranges of likely values where possible.  The cost
 estimates are based on the best available evidence  and best professional judgment about  the
 controls likely to  be imposed.  In some instances, however, these controls may  be insufficient
 to meet either current or future water quality standards, and additional more stringent controls
could be adopted. The cost estimates do not include any such additional controls because of the
difficulty of estimating their magnitude.  To the extent that additional controls are needed to
meet water quality standards, there  would be additional costs.
                                        ES-2

-------
  Sector-Specific Costs

        Table ES-1 presents information on current and planned expenditures associated with the
  current  implementation of the existing CWA  requirements.   Table  ES-2 summarizes  the
  incremental costs of the Initiative. Table ES-3 presents information on the potential cost savings
  (or costs avoided) compared with a stringent interpretation of CWA requirements  Table  ES-4
  summarizes  the current and potential  spending under a  stringent interpretation  of CWA
  requirements.  The annual cost of major provisions is presented in Figure ES-1 l  The hiehliehts
  from the tables are as follows:

        »     Private sources will likely incur incremental costs of $1.6 billion to $3.5 billion
               per year, but these costs are  substantially less than under  existing statutory
               requirements for storm water controls.  The major new cost items, as  shown in
               Table ES-2,  are the storm water  controls ($345 to $1,670 million per year)
               nonpomt  source  controls/watersheds ($233  to $388 million),  groundwater
               protection ($150 to $600  million per year) and the permit fee program ($290
               million per year).  These additional costs are much smaller than the projected
               $15.7 billion to $17.5 billion in avoided storm water control costs for both Phase
               I and  Phase H (see Table ES-3).   These savings represent the projected cost
               difference between the Initiative and a stringent interpretation of the existing
               CWA requirements.  One area with potentially significant cost implications that
               is not included in the current estimates is the cost of complying with future water
               quality standards and toxic pollutant control.   These costs are  not estimated
              because of the difficulty in predicting  whether and how these provisions will be
              implemented. Figure ES-2 presents this information graphically.

        +     Agriculture will likely incur incremental costs of $595 to $985 million per year
              net of savings from reduced use of fertilizers and pesticides.  Farmers will incur
              these costs to control agricultural runoff by using best management practices on
              farms that are located on impaired or threatened water bodies.  Net increases in
              costs are shown graphically in Figure ES-4.

        >      Municipalities will likely incur incremental costs of $1.2 billion to $2.1 billion
              per year, as shown in Table ES-2, but they will realize savings from changes in
              the storm water provisions.  As  shown in Table  ES-3, the storm water control
              provisions (Phase I and Phase II) will produce savings of between $0.76 billion
              and  $0.85 billion per year from  a  stringent interpretation of current  CWA
              requirements.  The CSO provisions will codify the final CSO Policy (estimated
              to cost $3.45 billion annually) and  will save municipalities an estimated  $10.7
              billion  per year compared with the projected compliance costs under a stringent
              interpretation of the current CWA requirements. Total municipal cost savings or
   1 Mid-points of ranges are used in preparing figures. The numbers in figures and tables may not match due
to rounding.

                                          ES-3

-------
             costs avoided are estimated at $11.5 billion to $11.6 billion per year. Figure ES-
             3 presents this information graphically.

      »      States will likely incur incremental costs of $416 million to implement numerous
             new provisions.  The two major cost elements are: $118 million for monitoring
             and $188 million for NPDES enforcement and permitting. The states will receive
             about $301 million annually in fees collected from National Pollutant Discharge
             Elimination System  (NPDES) permittees.  Thus, the net increase in costs for
             states is about $115 million per year, most of which is associated with implement-
             ing the NPS provisions.  See also Figure ES-5 for a graphical presentation.

      »-      Federal agencies will incur  additional  costs of approximately  $118 to $210
             million  to implement and comply with the nonpoint  source (NPS) and watershed
             provisions.2  The Department of Energy estimated an overall incremental annual
             cost of $520 million  for the Initiative's provisions.   Costs for remediating
             abandoned mines are estimated to be between $330 million and $1,100 million
             per year.  These  estimates are presented in Table ES-2.  Major savings over
             current CWA requirements will occur as a result of a more targeted approach to
             remediation  of  abandoned mine sites that affect surface water  quality.   Net
             impacts on federal agencies are a cost savings of between $1.1 billion and $3.5
             billion annually  compared with a stringent interpretation of existing law, as shown
             in Table ES-3.  Figure ES-6 presents this information graphically.

Provision-Specific Costs

       The impacts of major provisions of the Initiative are summarized below (see also Figure
ES-1):

       Nonpoint Source Control/Watershed Approach - The implementation of the NPS
management programs for both agricultural and non-agricultural (urban) areas will cost pnvate
entities and  municipalities an estimated $828 million to $1.37 billion per year, net of cost
savings from reduced fertilizer  and  pesticides usage.  States will oversee the development of
NPS programs at  a  cost  of  $92 million  per year.   Federal agency costs, meanwhile,  are
estimated  to be between  $118 million and $210 million  per year.  Figure  ES-4 presents
information separately for agriculture.

       Storm  Water - EPA estimates that the control  of storm water discharges, under a
stringent interpretation  of the 1987  CWA, would impose  large costs on private sources


    2 USDA's Soil Conservation Service has indicated that if implementation is their responsibility, the cost would
range between $211 and $540 million per year to assist the farmers with implementing NPS control measures. Also
excluded are permitting costs that the Forest Service has estimated to apply to federal lands ($716 to $718 million)
under a provision of S. 1114 that required reissuance of all Forest Service permits on an accelerated basis. Under
 the Initiative, permits would be reissued on existing schedules and therefore not result in a significant cost increase.
                                           ES-4

-------
 (approximately $20.2 billion) and municipalities (between $3.4 and $5.3 billion), as shown in
 Table ES-4.  The Initiative presents a more targeted storm water plan that, compared with the
 stringent plan, would save private sources between $15.7 billion and $17.5 billion per year and
 would save municipalities an estimated $0.76 billion to $0.85 billion per year for both Phase I
 and Phase II.  The total projected impacts of the storm water provisions, therefore, are savings
 in the range of $16.5 billion to $18.4 billion per year.

       CSOs  - The current CSO Policy, negotiated with the municipalities, environmental
 groups and states, is estimated to cost about $3.45 billion per year. Full implementation of the
 CSO  requirements,  under a stringent interpretation of the CWA, could cost as much as $14.14
 billion. The Initiative is proposing to codify the more cost-effective, site-specific CSO control
 strategy that could potentially save municipalities about $10.7 billion per year in avoided costs.

       Toxics Control - Under the  Initiative's toxics provision, EPA would have additional
 opportunity to limit releases  of the most  toxic and bioaccumulative  pollutants in  certain
 circumstances.  The Initiative would  also refocus the development of water quality  criteria and
 standards.  The Administration's approach would encourage examining multi-media strategies
 to restrict or ban the discharge of toxic pollutants, which would allow the Agency the flexibility
 to select the most cost-effective controls.   The toxics provision is estimated  to cost Federal
 agencies, including  EPA, between $66 million  and $105 million per year.

       Discharge Fees - The Initiative would require states (and EPA, in states administered by
 EPA) to have in place a permit fee system that  would produce sufficient revenues to fully fund
 the NPDES, pretreatment, and sludge programs. EPA estimates that unfunded costs associated
 with these programs total $394 million per year and would have to be collected from industrial
 and municipal dischargers.  States would receive approximately $301 million in revenues, with
 the remainder  going to EPA for the permits it issues.

       Groundwater Protection - The Initiative acknowledges the connection between surface
 water contamination and groundwater quality and establishes the protection of groundwater as
 a specific goal of surface water programs. EPA believes that implementation of these provisions
 will help protect groundwater and drinking water supplies from contamination originating from
 surface water  discharges.  Costs to private sources responsible for this  cleanup will average
between $150  million and $600 million per year.

       Pollution Prevention Planning - The Initiative would give EPA and authorized  States
the discretionary authority to require pollution prevention plans as a condition of NPDES permits
for industrial users.   EPA estimates that at most 6,000 permittees each  year would  be required
to prepare such plans, at an annual cost of between $60 million and $120 million.  The cost of
implementing such plans has not been estimated. States would be responsible for  writing this
provision into NPDES permits and for reviewing plans prepared by the permittees. Estimates
of these costs,  however, are not available because not all facilities will be required to implement
such plans.
                                         ES-5

-------
       Domestic Sewage Exclusion - The Initiative would retain the domestic sewage exclusion
(DSE) for facilities subject to local limits set by publicly owned treatment works (POTWs),
national standards,  or the 304(m) plan.  Facilities  subject to toxic reduction action  plans
(TRAPs) by their POTWs  would also be exempt, as would households and noncommercial and
nonindustrial facilities that discharge de minimis amounts  of waste.  EPA estimates that the
impacts of these additional measures on dischargers will average $282 million per year.

       Enforcement - The enforcement provisions in the Initiative include a variety of measures
that provide additional incentives to assure compliance, to ensure that penalties more closely
match the economic benefits of noncompliance, and to facilitate  the processing of violation
cases. The Initiative also  recommends a waiver of sovereign immunity for federal facilities in
violation of Clean Water Act provisions.  Fines and penalties for violations are not economic
costs  but instead are considered a transfer to the federal government.  The new enforcement
provisions are estimated to cost States an additional $90 million per year.

       State Revolving Fund/Construction Grants - The revised state revolving  fund (SRF)
and construction grants program will impose limited additional costs. State costs are estimated
at $8 million per year.

       Monitoring - The  monitoring provisions will largely impact State governments, with an
estimated cost  of $118 million per  year.   Federal agency  impacts are  negligible, with the
exception of the Forest Service, which will incur costs of approximately $37 million per year
to perform the  monitoring function on federal lands managed by that agency.

       Abandoned Mines - Under a stringent interpretation of the current CWA provisions, an
estimated 500,000 sites would require remediation at a cost of between $1.38 billion and $4.58
billion per year.  Because a vast majority of these mines do not contribute to water quality
problems, the Initiative introduces a targeted approach so as to achieve the greatest environmen-
tal improvement for  the  limited federal resources that may be available.  The costs of this
approach are estimated at between $330 million and $1,100  million per year.  The net impact
of the Initiative is,  therefore, a savings of between $1.1 billion and $3.5 billion per year.

       To summarize, the annual incremental cost of the Initiative on all sectors ranges from
$5.0  billion to $9.6 billion.  The annual cost savings  (or costs avoided) by all sectors range
between $29.1 and $33.8 billion.

Potential Cost  Savings From Economic Incentives - Effluent Trading

       The Initiative contains provisions mat would encourage the establishment of mechanisms
for trading  pollution reduction among sources, similar to the trading provisions  of the 1990
Glean Air Act Amendments.  A preliminary analysis by EPA indicates that trading could achieve
pollution reduction at significantly lower costs.  These potential decreases in costs should be
viewed as future costs avoided  (or not incurred) because  dischargers  will not be installing
additional controls to meet new requirements. These potential cost savings should not be.viewed
                                          ES-6

-------
as decreasing other costs discussed in this report but instead would represent reductions in the
cost of additional controls needed for growth or to meet water quality standards. The decreased
costs of pollution prevention and control, by type of trading, were estimated as follows:

Point source/nonpoint source            $611 million to $5.6 billion
Point source/point source               $8.4 million to $1.9 billion
Nonpoint source/nonpoint source        Potential exists but limited data
Pretreatment                           $39 million
       TOTAL                         $658 million to $7.5 billion

Physical Measures of National Benefits

       This report contains summaries of the physical benefits of individual provisions contained
in the Initiative (e.g., toxics control, NPS prevention, abandoned mines, etc.).  The benefits
descriptions for the individual provisions are intended to indicate the scope of the problems
addressed by the Initiative (in terms of water quality and human and ecological impacts) and the
magnitude of the benefits obtained from addressing these problems. Results from these benefits
analyses indicate that the Initiative's provisions could cause substantial improvements in water
quality.

       *      NPS controls have a high or medium likelihood of producing measurable water
              quality improvements in  52 percent of impaired or threatened  rivers and 63
              percent of impaired or threatened lakes  acres based on data from 28 states.  For
              all 54 states and territories, EPA projects that about 156,200 river miles and 7.1
              million lake acres will show measurable water quality improvements.
       *      Storm water control  can reduce loadings of urban pollutants (sediment, toxics,
              nutrients) by 75  to 80 percent in developing areas and by 15 to 25 percent in
              areas already developed.

       *      Implementation of EPA's CSO Policy will provide adequate treatment for  over
              one billion gallons of raw sewage, urban  runoff, and industrial wastewater that
              are currently discharged  without treatment during ;m average year (reducing
              pollutant loadings of 2,050 million pounds of total suspended solids (TSS) and
              445 million pounds of biological oxygen demand (BOD) annually).

       >      Further control over the discharge of toxic and/or bioaccumulative pollutants will
              reduce impacts on human health and aquatic life impacts.

Monetized Benefits:  Urban Areas

       EPA estimates further that the aggregate benefits of pollution, control in urban areas will
eventually produce quantifiable benefits of between $0.8 billion and $6.0 billion per year (Table
ES-6).  The range recognizes the uncertainty associated with these estimates. For example, the
upper end of the range may be an underestimate in the extreme case where the new provisions

                                          ES-7

-------
are 100 percent effective, households care very much about the resultant improvements relative
to the other waters in their state, and the unquantified benefits turn out to be significant relative
to the quantified benefits.  Similarly, the lower end of the range may be an overestimate in the
extreme event that the new provisions fail to improve water quality to fishable and swimmable
levels, or the changes in water quality have no effect on the economic activities of consumers
and producers.

       The benefit estimates are based on household valuation of clean water for a variety of
purposes.  However, several important additional categories of benefits which are either not
quantified  because relevant data  are  not available or are not amenable  to estimation via
quantitative techniques will also accrue. Examples include:
>
»•
>
>
             Enhanced recreational swimming and boating in marine waters.
             Improved recreational hunting opportunities as watershed habitats improve.
             Avoided costs for water storage, flood control and water purification as natural
             systems improve.
             Reduced dredging costs as watershed and wet weather programs reduce siltation.
             Lower  costs for sediment  remediation  over  time as toxics and permitting
             provisions are adopted.
       >     Increases in biodiversity and overall ecological integrity.

       Limitations. The analysis of the economic benefits focusing on urban areas draws upon
information provided  by a number of  disparate data sources,  and relies upon a number of
assumptions. The synthesis of information introduces considerable uncertainty into the final
numeric values.  Major sources of uncertainty that limit our ability to be confident in the
numeric results include: (1) the actual extent of impaired waters; (2) the method of attributing
responsibility for impairment; (3) our assumptions about the efficacy of the provisions; and (4)
the reliance upon secondary sources of information when estimating the economic values of
environmental quality.  The absence of reliable information on all of these elements plays a
critical role in  our ability to draw conclusions about the benefits that will result from the
Initiative.

       One of the more significant points of uncertainty in the analysis relates to the monetary
valuation of economic benefits for the dominant benefit category— the enhanced freshwater
recreation,  aesthetics,  and  non-use benefits that ensue with the  proposed water  quality
improvements.   The  absence  of  alternative data  sources constrained  us to make use of a
published, yet dated, contingent valuation research study that measured a household's use and
non-use values for national and, by apportionment techniques, more localized improvements in
freshwater rivers and lakes.  Criticism has been levied against the validity of empirical results
for non-use values derived using prior contingent valuation research methods.  Several issues
raised in the ongoing debate about  this valuation method bear directly upon the interpretation of
the numeric results provided by our source materials.
                                         ES-8

-------
       Independent of this debate,  further uncertainties are introduced by  transferring  the
research results to the policies and environmental concerns addressed by the Initiative. The wide
range of values demonstrates an attempt to capture the impact of these uncertainties on the
numeric estimate.  All told, it is difficult to conclude whether the presented numeric ranges
underestimate or overestimate the actual benefits.. We suggest that the numerical results best
serve to indicate the overall order-of-magnitude of the benefits. Based upon our experience in
undertaking the analysis, we can further conclude that considerable gaps persist in our ability
to measure and evaluate the relationships between  water quality conditions and economic
activities, even twenty years after the passage of the principal legislation designed to identify and
address water pollution problems.  The Administration's Initiative contains provisions to help
rectify this situation in the future.

Costs: Urban Areas

       Provisions in the Initiative that address urban areas are loosely defined to include storm
water Phase I and Phase II, CSOs and toxics controls. The annualized costs of these provisions
for all sectors is estimated to be between $9.9 billion and $13.9 billion, as shown in Table ES-5.

Net Benefits: Urban Areas

       The monetized benefits of the Initiative ($0.8 billion to $6.0 billion), assuming benefits
are realized  immediately,  contrast with between $9.9 billion to $13.9  billion in incremental
annualized costs for urban areas.

       However, benefits are unlikely to be realized immediately. To illustrate how the gradual
attainment of the benefits may influence the benefit-cost comparison, the  figures in Tables ES-5
and ES-6 show the annualized monetary  costs and benefits from control of urban sources under
proposed and pending spending. In Table ES-6, two of the three aggregate benefit estimates
provide for the gradual attainment of benefits, applying  different discount rates to an assumed
future  stream of benefits.   The selection of the two discount  rates reflects Administration
guidelines on the application of discounting to costs and benefits (seven  percent),  as compared
with the  use of a  social rate of time preference (three percent).  The  discounted annualized
benefits are  some twenty to thirty percent lower than the annualized benefit estimate that fails
to account for  the expected delays in achieving tangible  water quality improvements.   This
serves to demonstrate the  sensitivity of the results to both  the time and discounting features of
the analysis.

        Comparing the annualized costs  and benefits under any of the three annualized benefit
 estimation scenarios, it is apparent that  the range of estimated monetary costs and benefits do
 not presently overlap. Despite information of this type,  the Administration feels it is important
 to proceed with the Initiative for several reasons.  As stated throughout the text, and documented
 in the supplemental materials,  there are great uncertainties associated with both the cost and
 benefit estimates that are not captured in the presentation of the numerical results.  For example,
 although the national cost estimates have attempted to account for targeting of watersheds in


                                           ES-9

-------
need of improvement and emphasized prevention measures over command-and-control strategies,
there are uncertainties in the analysis because of the difficulty of fully accounting for the
consequences of providing flexibility in the identification of problems and solutions.  There are
also a number of tangible benefits for which monetary estimates have not been developed.  So
as to better inform decisionmakers and the public in the future EPA is proposing a comprehen-
sive benefit-cost study of the pollution controls in the CWA reauthorization. This study will
reduce the uncertainties  surrounding the benefits and  cost estimates.

       Despite the uncertainties, an important contribution of the economic analysis  has been
its ability to document the significant  savings the Initiative is proposing compared with the
requirements called for in the existing legislation. In addition, considerable effort was given to
developing cost-effective policies where new efforts are needed to achieve the goals of the Clean
Water Act.  Therefore, the Initiative demonstrates a genuine effort to achieve cost-effective
regulatory management approaches to improving  the nation's polluted  waters.    Equally
important, the public's right to enjoy clean waters, and the demonstration of their preferences
through  environmentally  protective federal  legislation,  have  served as  inputs  into  the
development of Administration policy.   Strong public support for additional pollution control
programs persists, and the Initiative will address what the Administration believes are the most
significant remaining problems.
                                         ES-10

-------

 I
i
CO
 o
CO

-------
2
I

-------

   S $£
>  
l
If !
V?

o
5^
i—i
, i
fs,.
irT




|| TOTALS
1
g
j^
o
tfl
fc<
<&
c
i
S
13

C
E
JD
& S
! :i
S ^
1 t
"o s.
S — 7
1 1
8 «
a -o
60 B
.S
*O *S
S c^
•0 09
CM 2
30 g
* 1 I
•3 ~ o
1.& &
•a o a>
•l'i -i •
§.§ 1 1
03 M< ,.™
>-^ S 9) ^
•g H 2*0
o E o nj
oj O <*3 ,2
1 Cost savings (or cost
$611 million and $5,61
2 Reflects the revenues
Source: U.S.EPA, Of

-------
                               a'g
                                      s
                        ^H II  00

                        8    S
t
 o o
^ a a










s
.3
1
5














P
®
*T
OO
"I
1
w i
1 Tf
i ^
Os M .-?
V*





6
I



(

3
                                                                I
             I
                                                                CO
I
I

-------
                                   Table ES-5
Summary of Aggregate Anmialized Costs  from Control of Urban Sources Under the
Initiative and Pending Spending (CSOs, Storm water, Toxics)
Cost Category
Municipal Costs
Phase I Storm water
Phase n Storm water
CSO Controls
CZARA Non-Point Controls
Pending Spending (Great Lakes,
Sludge)
Subtotal Municipal
Private Sector
Phase I Storm water
Phase II Storm water
Pollution Prevention Plans
Domestic Sewage Exclusion
Nonpoint Source Controls
Subtotal Private Sector
Total Quantified Costs in Urban Areas
Range: Low - High
(Millions of 1993 $)
$ 1,650 - $ 2,555
$ 1,030 - $ 1,910
$ 3,450
$390- $590
$90
$ 6,610 - $ 8,595
$2,360- $2,850
$ 345 •- $ 1,670
$ 60 - $ 120
$ 280
$ 233 - $ 388
$3,278- $5,308
$ 9,888 •- $ 13,903
Non-Quantified Costs
State Administration Costs (Urban portion of $650m)
Federal Compliance (Urban portion of $945m) - excludes abandoned mines.
Groundwater Controls (Urban portion of $150m to $600m)
Further Water Quality Criteria and Standards and sediment criteria
Toxics Bans
Other Pending Spending (e.g., Great Lakes, Pulp and Paper Effluent Guidelines, Air MACT
standards)
Source: Tables ES-1 and ES-2.

-------
                                            Table ES-6
 Summary of Aggregate Annualized Benefits from Control of Urban Sources Under the
 Initiative and Pending Spending (CSOs, Storm water, Toxics)
                             Benefit Category
                                          Quantified Benefits
Range: Low - High
(Millions of 1993 $)
| Freshwater Recreational Fishing and Swimming (use and nonuse)
Marine Recreational Fishing (use only)
(I Marine Nonconsumptive Recreation (use only)
Marine and Freshwater Commercial Fishing
Withdrawal or Diversionary Uses
Human Health Effects (from risks associated with exposure to pollutants via
swimming activity and seafood consumption)1
Sub-total: Quantified Benefits2
I Assuming immediate attainment of benefits3
1 (i) Annualized Benefits (no lag and no discounting, thus a
1 simple summation of individual categories)
Assuming a gradual attainment of benefits over the first 15 year period that
all Urban Source Controls are adopted.4
(ii) Annualized Benefits (seven percent discount rate, gradual
attainment over first 15 years)
(iii) Annualized benefits (three percent discount rate, gradual
attainment over first 15 years)
$650-
$40-
, $30-
$40-
$20-
$40-
(i) $ 820
(ii) $ 560
(iii) $ 660
$ 4,670
$440
$300
$ 190
$ 80
$320
-$6,000
- $ 4,100
- $ 4,900
Non-Quantified Benefits
- Marine Recreational Swimming (nonhealth effects)
- Other Human Health Effects hi Marine and Freshwaters (see Note 1)
  - Recreational Hunting- Freshwater Nonconsumptive Recreation (see Note 1)
  - Marine Recreational Boating
  - Other Non-use Benefits (Marine Waters - see Note 1)
  - Other avoided costs (e.g., water storage, dredging, damages from floods)
  - Restoration of biodiversity and ecosystem integrity
  uiven miormauon ana metnoas used to calculate the quantified benefits, some portion of the benefits associated
with these categories may be captured in the monetary range ascribed to freshwater recreation fishing and
swimming.
* Assumes no double counting of benefits or substitution effects between different categories when developing
aggregate national estimates. Also assumes that all lower and upper ends of the range for each quantified category
describe the aggregate lower and upper bound estimate. Absent information on the distribution or probability of
attaining benefits defined by the estimated range, we can not calculate a "most likely" estimate.
3 Assuming no lag between implementation of controls, recovery of natural ecological systems, and economic
behavior  that forms the basis for the economic benefit measures.
4 These estimates of the economic benefits are more  appropriate to use when comparing quantified costs and
benefits,  given the anticipated lag time between introduction of the  control measures and full realization of the
environmental and economic benefits. The calculated annualized figure is based on assuming a gradual attainment
of benefits up through year fifteen, and a constant future benefits stream after the fifteenth year has been reached.

-------
      CO
      c
      o
      o
co  .,
LLJ   03

 0)
      g

     O
                                o>   —

                               £   5
                               O   GO
 t/>

 ®   O   GO
.£   CO   Q_

5   O   Z
—   (1)
-=>   CO
§   (0
co   m
                  CO
                  O)
                  O)
                  T—

                  CO
                  c

                  O
                                                                             3

                                                                            O
                                    OJ,

                                    "(5
                                    CO
                                    o
                                    a.
                                    o
                                    c
                                    o
                                    O
                                                                                      0)
                                                                                      c
                                                                                      0)
                                             o
                               0)
                                                                                      <0
                                                                                      •55
                                                                                      o
                                                                                      o
                               «*—
                               i_
                               o
                                                                                   0)
                                                                                   llg
                                                                                   E I o
                                                                                   CO O "
                                           (0
                                             -
                                             *i  O
                                           2 S  £
                                           Q.    Q.
                                           _ 0) "^r
                                           0*0^


                                           8 ^*  *-


                                           S "5  I
                                           •S c  ™
                                                                                   T- CM CO

-------
LJJ

 
      03
     Q_
      • •
      CO


      o
     O
     J—
    a.
O)
     O
     CO
     O

    O
     13

     C
     C
                                     
                                                                                     2
                                                                                      to
                                                                                      o
                                                                                      o
                                                                                   (0
                                                                                   i  «
                                                                                   E  -
                                                                                   «  >
c o *-
 -a
                                                                                  ^  o c
                                                                                  £ a :D

                                                                                  T^ c\T 
-------
  05
  Q.
  "o
      (/)
      c
CO   O
  8
 o
 O

to
 O
O

"co
                (/I
                CO
                O)
                O)
            c
            o
                              
                                                                                  

                                                                                  2
                                                                                 73
                                                                                 a>
                                                                                 •g

                                                                                 1
                                                                                 (0
                                                                             u
                                                                              .2 c
w ^ o
&|B
                                                                              oi£
       8 = ?

       Sg«
      1 « 5
       " o c
      — Q D

      ^ cJ" S"

-------
     CD
     O
     CD
     CO
     C
     O
     "

CO  >
LJLJ
 0
     o

     CL
     5—


S>oT
U_
      0)
      O
     O

     "as
£2
to
CO
O)
O)
                                       CO   «
                                       CL   (0
                                       z   m
                                                      CM
                                            LO
                    to
                                                  CM
                                                                      CO
                                                                      
                                                                             (0 >
                                                                o
CO  O  -5

"S  «  c
                                                                             O O  
-------
 0)
 0
V)
 o
•9   o
CO  fi-
ll!
 CD   O
 D  "*-•
 « 2 -5

3 1 «=

 o SS
 Q. ^ «
 2 o a>
 Q.   QL
H_ 

^ o c
£ Q D

-------
     CD
     CD
     o
     C
     CD
     O)
     05
     0
    T3
     CD
    LL

CD  g
  1   ^:
co .2
yu
    Q_

U-  O
     O

     "w
     O
     O

     "as
     c
                 ..
                 o
                 .c
                 +-«
                 O
                                   CO
CO
Q_
0
CO
(0
CD
JO

"o
CO
O)
O)

                                                      OJ
                            I  g

                            Is
                            2  £
                            Cl. CL
                            O  ®
                            W  4-J
                            •s  •-
                            o  •?;
                            O  .-1
                            »  tS
                                                                  11
                                                                  ^"•s *-"**
                                                                  T- CJ

-------
1.0    Introduction

       This report  summarizes  the costs and benefits of provisions contained in President
Clinton's  Clean Water Initiative.   As noted in Executive Orders  12866 and 12893,  such
comparisons are necessary because resources committed to implement the Initiative can be used
for alternative productive purposes. Therefore, the opportunity costs of these resources should
be compared with the economic benefits.  Such comparisons  should be used  to help fashion
policies that offer the largest possible net benefits.

       In addition to estimated costs and benefits, many factors need to be taken into account
in supporting an environmental initiative.   These  include large uncertainties and  gaps in
estimating benefits and costs, the distribution of benefits and costs among  segments of the
American people, and support  of the public for environmental controls.  Regarding  these
matters, the Administration believes that it is appropriate to be on the  side of environmental
caution because of the large uncertainty about the effectiveness of proposed controls, and about
the benefits and costs generally.  The Administration also recognizes the continuing support for
the Clean Water  Act (CWA) both in Congress and  by the general  public.   Finally, the
Administration believes that cleaner water is especially important because it provides benefits
that  are distributed broadly among all Americans, irrespective of income levels or ethnic
background.

       The Initiative will require incremental expenditures of $5 to $9.6 billion per  year.
However, compared with the costs of a stringent interpretation of the current law, the Initiative
will yield potential savings  (or avoid future costs) of $29 to $33.8 billion.

-------
 2.     Approach

        Scope. This report presents the costs of the Initiative, measures of physical benefits of
 the Initiative, and estimates of the costs and monetized benefits of provisions of the Initiative
 applicable to urban areas only.

        Costs are reported in two different ways.  First, they are provided by sector: (1) private
 sources (i.e., industry,  commercial and private individuals), (2) agriculture (farmers), (3)
 municipalities  (including operators  of  public wastewater  treatment  facilities), (4)  state
 governments, through their water programs, and (5) federal agencies. It is recognized that some
 of the effects of the Initiative are  transfers rather than costs.  Second, costs are provided for
 each major provision of the Initiative. For comparison with monetized benefits in urban areas,
 incremental costs are also reported for three general provisions:  storm water Phase I and II,
 combined sewer overflow controls, and toxics.

       Benefits  of the Initiative are reported  in  physical terms, such  as  stream  miles  of
 improvements. For urban areas only, benefits are reported in monetized terms; we  account for
 a large variety of  benefit  categories, the  most  important  being recreational  fishing and
 swimming.

       Estimates of the Initiative's impact were developed by the U.S. Environmental Protection
 Agency (EPA) Office of Water in consultation with EPA's Office of Policy, Planning, and
 Evaluation and other federal agencies, including the U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA),
 U.S. Department of the Interior (DOI), U.S. Department of Commerce (DOC) -  National
 Oceanographic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA), U.S. Department of Defense (DOD),
 and U.S. Department of Energy (DOE), as well as with the White House Office of Management
 and Budget (OMB), Council of Economic Advisers (CEA), and National Economic  Council
 (NEC).

       Data  Sources.  All of the costing work was done in a similar fashion.  Given the time
 available to prepare the estimates, we could not commission specific  new  analyses of, for
 example, compliance with the CSO policy on actual or model municipal systems. Instead, our
 general approach was to first examine the literature of existing studies pertaining to a given
 issue.  Typically this process identified at least a few relevant studies. Some provisions (e.g.,
 nonpoint source controls and certain trading scenarios) had many relevant analyses from which
 to draw cost data or information. Other provisions (e.g., the toxics provisions) had few directly
 relevant studies for comparison purposes.

       The cost estimates are thus largely built on secondary data sources and limited "original"
 analysis. Regulatory analyses prepared by EPA for specific program actions also  were quite
 useful data sources.  These included regulatory impact analyses (RIAs) for the Agency's CSO
 Policy;  the Pulp and Paper and Offshore  Oil  and Gas Effluent Guideline  regulations; the
Economic Impact Analysis of the CZARA; the RIA for the Great Lakes Water Quality Initiative
proposal; and previous reauthorization studies conducted by the Agency in  1991-1992 (draft

-------
studies were prepared covering storm water, CSOs, and several other topics).

       All of the literature and secondary sources described here were used as the basis for our
Initiative cost estimates.  When possible,  estimates were drawn "as is" from the reports.  In
other cases, modifications and re-analyses were required. The specific procedures are described
in more detail in later sections of this report.

       Baseline. Some provisions of the  1987 Clean Water Act Amendments have not yet
been implemented.  Some provisions of the Initiative will impose new responsibilities and costs
beyond those called for  in the  1987 Amendments.  Others scale back obligations under the
Amendments  and  will save the private sector, municipalities, and  the  federal government
billions of dollars while not compromising environmental quality.  Therefore, it is legitimate to
view the baseline from which costs of the Initiative are estimated in two ways: as increments
above current and pending spending or as reductions in costs from stringent interpretations of
the 1987 CWA  The stringent interpretations reflect the reading of the law proposed by various
outside groups but do not represent EPA's best interpretation of the law. However, while EPA
believes that these interpretations are stringent and inflexible, they could potentially be adopted
by a court in litigation challenging  EPA's interpretation.  This report carefully  distinguishes
estimates from these two baselines.

       The analysis presented here  centers on five "sectors" that the Initiative is expected to
 affect- the private sector, municipalities,  agriculture, state governments, and federal agencies.
 Each  of these sectors has  been the  subject of separate analytical efforts, which are described
 briefly below:

        >     Private Sector - The impacts of the Initiative on the private sector (commercial
              and industrial) are based on analyses prepared by the Office of Water. Impacts
              on the private  sector  are largely estimated in terms of annualized costs.

        >     Municipalities - The major impacts of the Initiative on municipalities are a result
              of the combined sewer overflow (CSO) and storm water provisions.  The Office
              of Water developed estimates of the costs of compliance with these provisions.

        >     Agriculture - The impacts of nonpoint  source provisions in the Initiative on
               agriculture, primarily farmers, are estimated using the methodology for estimating
               costs for the CZARA  guidance.   These are presented separately to show the
               magnitude of the costs  on this sector.

        »     State Governments - Estimates of the Initiative impacts on state water programs
               were prepared by the Office of Water, in consultation with  water programs
               officials from seven states (Maryland, Missouri, North Carolina, Nevada, Ohio,
               South Carolina, and Texas).  The state analysis considered the administrative
               costs of new provisions on the state water programs as well as unfunded 1987
                CWA requirements. Pre-1987 expenditures, estimated to be about $2.7 billion

-------
              per year for administration and compliance (EPA, 1990b) are not included here
              because the cost of complying with current and future water quality standards
              could not be estimated.

        *     Federal  Agencies - The impacts of the Initiative on  federal agencies  were
              developed by the respective agencies and reported to EPA.  Impacts include the
              costs of additional staff (including salaries, benefits, and overhead), as well as
              additional extramural contract support necessary to implement and comply with
              the Initiative provisions.  Federal agencies represented in the analysis include
              EPA, USDA Soil  Conservation Service (SCS) and Forest Service (FS)  DOI
              NOAA, DOD, and DOE.1

       Consistency in Benefit and Cost Estimation.  To assure that urban area benefits and
 costs are comparable, a number of steps v/ere taken.  The costs and  benefits  are presented in
 annualized 1993 dollars.  Benefits are  discounted using three different rates (zero, three, and
 seven percent),  and assuming  that they are  fully in place in  15 years.   This procedure is
 necessary to account for the fact that benefits or costs experienced later in time are worth less
 than those experienced sooner. The nature of environmental risks is that it will take time to
 fully attain many of the projected water quality improvements and economic benefits.  Costs are
 annualized at seven percent.

       Uncertainties in Estimating Costs. To account for the uncertainty inherent in estimating
 costs for various provisions, we have used ranges of likely values where possible.  The cost
 estimates are based on best professional judgment about the controls likely to be imposed.  In
 some instances,  however, these controls may be insufficient to meet either current or future
 water quality standards,  and additional more  stringent control  could be  adopted.   The cost
 estimates do not include any such additional controls because of the difficulty of estimating their
 magnitude.  To the extent that additional controls are needed to meet  water quality standards
 there would be additional costs.                                                        '

       The remainder of this report presents the results  of cost and benefit  analyses of the
Initiative's provisions.
   1 Sources include: USDA (1994); DOI (1994); DOD (1993a and 1993b); NOAA (1993); and DOE (1993).

                                          4

-------
3.0   Nonpoint Source Controls

      The Initiative's provisions would require all states to strengthen their nonpoint source
(NFS) management program for impaired, threatened, or special protection areas.  EPA would
develop guidance for states to use in developing and implementing their  nonpoint source
management program which would require nonpoint "sources" to adopt incremental compliance
actions, including best available management measures.

      As an alternative to a comprehensive NPS program, states could address NFS pollution
problems under a watershed approach using site-sjjecific plans adapted to local conditions.  EPA
estimates  that under either alternative, similar sources would  be addressed using similar
mitigation methods. Controls  under a watershed approach would be developed following an
assessment of water quality  problems at the  local level, and  would be more targeted in
comparison with the comprehensive NPS program. Therefore, the NPS control costs would
probably be somewhat less  under the watershed approach,  although the order of magnitude of
costs would be similar using either approach.

       States will have 2l/z  years  to  develop and submit their revised  NPS management
programs, with implementation to occur over a subsequent 5-year period.

       3.1   Private Sources

       Nonpoint sources that these provisions address can be divided into several "sectors," each
of which may contribute one or more categories of pollutant loadings in a variety of ways. The
major NPS sectors are shown in Table 1, with siome of the activities that contribute nonpoint
pollutant loadings and some of the control alternatives that may be called upon to mitigate  them.

       ERG, 1993, developed estimates of the  costs of a national NPS control program using
models  developed  for  EPA  in  support  of  the  1990  Coastal Zone  Act  Reauthorization
Amendments (CZARA)  (RCG/Hagler,  Bailly, 1992; hereafter referenced  as the CZARA
Regulatory Impact Analysis, or RIA).  These models calculate the costs and impacts of NPS
controls in the above sectors.  The CZARA RIA estimated the costs of control in the U.S.
coastal  zone, which was defined to include counties in which at  least 15 percent of land area
drains into  coastal  waters.  Costs of controlling  nonpoint sources in the coastal zone were
estimated to be between $260 million and $436 million per year (see Table 2).

       To estimate the cost of the Initiative's NPS provisions, a coastal NPS program is assumed
to be fully implemented in the coastal zone,  as required under CZARA.  The focus of the
Initiative NPS provisions will therefore be on nonpoint sources in the noncoastal zone.

       Table 3 shows a marked difference between the coastal and noncoastal zone in terms of
population density and land area.   Accounting for 82 percent of the land area and only 48
percent of the population,  the population density in the noncoastal zone, at  41.4 persons per
 square mile, is only one-fifth that of the coastal  areas.  Because of this, agricultural and forestry

-------
 NPS control measures will be relatively more important in the noncoastal zone, and urban runoff
 measures will be relatively less important.

        Cost estimates developed for the coastal zone were extrapolated to the noncoastal zone
 using appropriate factors such as the noncoastal zone's share of land area, population, farmland,
 cultivated cropland, and so on.  A detailed methodology can be found  in ERG, 1993.2  The
 CZARA RIA's costs used for the extrapolation were based on unit control costs (e.g., $/acre)
 and need estimates (e.g., percent of acres requiring treatment) that may differ between the
 coastal and  noncoastal zone. While values for these variables may differ between  the coastal
 and noncoastal  zone, time did  not permit the development of specific parameters  for the
 noncoastal zone.  In some cases, however, the coastal zone parameters are themselves based on
 national data, hence no additional bias is introduced by using them here.

        The  Initiative  recommends application  of NPS  management  measures in impaired,
 threatened, or special protection areas only, making it necessary to identify the sources located
 in such areas. Although no comprehensive data exists to link sources of nonpoint pollution to
 specific water body impairment, EPA's Section 305(b) survey  does provide estimates of the
 number of water bodies (river miles, lake acres, and  estuary square miles) that do not fully
 support their designated uses.   This  data was judged to be appropriate and to  provide a
 reasonable basis for estimating the extent of need for a national NPS control program.3 Because
 of the uncertainty  in predicting  the number of new sources  that would be impacted by  the
 Initiative, no attempt is made to estimate costs of NPS management measures for new sources.

       EPA's most recent Section 305(b) survey indicates that approximately 33 to 50 percent
 of water  bodies nationally do not support, only partially support, or threaten their designated
 uses (EPA, 1992).  ERG used these percentages to calculate the potential cost of nonurban NPS
 controls in impaired or threatened noncoastal watersheds from the cost estimates derived for the
 entire noncoastal zone.  In  urban  areas, the factor used to represent impaired or threatened
 waters was 25 percent.4
    2 For example, the costs of grazing management control in the coastal zone were estimated at $2.8 million per
year. The coastal zone accounts for 25.3 million of a total of $515.8 million grazing acres, or 4.9 percent of total.
The total costs of grazing controls nationally are $424.5 million ($2.8 million divided by 0.049).  Costs outside the
coastal zone are then $403.7 million.  In Table 2 these costs are further adjusted to account for the fact that NPS
controls would be required in impaired areas only.  Assuming that between 33 percent and 50 percent of grazing
acres in the noncoastal zone are impaired, the costs of grazing controls are between $133 million and $202 million.

     The 305(b) data indicate the water quality and impairment sources of water bodies assessed by the states.
Nationally, the assessed  percent of river miles, lake acres, and estuary square miles varies significantly.  EPA
assumes that the water bodies  assessed are reasonably representative of all water bodies nationally, i.e., neither
higher nor lower quality water bodies are over-represented in these data.

    4 Best Professional judgment applied to 305(b) data shows impairment in urban areas as follows: rivers (5
percent); lakes (14 percent); and estuaries (19 percent).  The sum of rivers and lakes is used a basis for percent
impairment.

-------
       The national costs of a NFS control program, extrapolated from the CZARA analysis of
costs in the coastal zone, were then adjusted to account for the fact that NFS controls would be
required in impaired or threatened areas only. The; percentage of land area requiring treatment
or the percentage of sources requiring control is assumed to be proportional to the percentage
of water bodies that are either impaired or threatened.  Thus, the costs of control in impaired
or threatened nonurban areas are estimated to be between 33 and 50 percent of the costs for a
national program in  noncoastal zone.  Similarly, the costs  of control in urban impaired or
threatened areas are estimated at 25 percent of the national costs. The costs of the NFS program
in threatened or impaired areas are shown in the final column of Table 2.

       Because the noncoastal zone is, relatively speaking, more rural than the coastal zone, the
nonpoint source control costs are dominated by agricultural sources, while control costs for
urban  sources are relatively less important.  In the noncoastal zone, agricultural controls are
estimated to account for between $1.06 billion and $1.83 billion, as shown in Table 20.  The
costs of nutrient and pesticide management,  while estimated at between $461 million and $845
million,  are largely  offset by  savings  in  chemical consumption  that  will  accompany the
application of these measures. Thus, total net costs for all sources are $595 to  $985 million per
year [$1.06 billion - $1.83 billion (from Table 20) less $461 million - $845 million (from Table
21)].

       Potential incremental cost for urban nonpoint sources due to hydromodification and storm
water  controls is estimated to range between $233 million and $388 million per year (Table 20).
Thus  the total incremental cost to all private sources  is between $0.83 billion and $1.37 billion
annually (sum of $595 million to $985  million'and $233 million to $388 million).   Current
expenditures on nonpoint sources are between $1 and $1.3 billion, as shown in Table  19.

       In a separate analysis, USDA's Soil Conservation Service  (SCS) has estimated that the
 agricultural NFS  controls alone will lower producers'  surplus in  the  agricultural sector by
 approximately $1.8 billion per year (USDA, 1994).  The annual increase in consumer cost for
 food is roughly equal to the decline in government subsidy payments.  This figure was derived
 using  an entirely different modeling methodology that simulates the impact of  the NFS  controls
 on the affected agricultural sectors.  This approach allows for the effects of increases in
 producers' costs for  bringing various commodities (e.g., crops, dairy, livestock) to market to
 filter through the economy. One reason for the considerably higher cost estimate compared with
 the extrapolation discussed above is that credits for savings in pesticides and nutrients  (through
 the nutrient and pesticide NFS management measure)  are considerably lower. This reflects
 differences between USDA and EPA beliefs concerning the potential for such measures to reduce
 chemical requirements.  USDA/SCS believes that these estimates are high and that available
 alternatives, if used, could result in lower costs.

        3.2   Municipalities

        The NFS control  provisions,  particularly  the urban runoff  measures,  will affect
 municipalities that  will be required to implement controls  for road,  highway, and bridge

-------
 maintenance, among  others.  Costs for these measures  are included in the costs for urban
 controls shown in Section 3.1, Private Sources.

        3.3   State Water Programs

        The NFS control provisions are estimated to cost state water programs $10 million per
 year, based on estimates derived in the State Program Costs study (EPA, 1993f).

        3.4   Federal Agencies

        The impacts of the  NPS  control and  watershed  provisions on federal agencies are
 estimated to range from $118 million to $210 million per year, as  shown in Table 4.5 These
 resources will be used by: USDA/FS to develop watershed management plans for federal forests;
 DOI, to assist  in identifying impaired  waters and preparing  NPS plans; EPA, to provide
 guidance to states on nonpoint sources and  watershed  management;  NOAA,  to  assist in
 watershed identification and designation; and DOD, to address NPS discharges from defense
 facilities.

        3.5   Benefits6

 Methodology

        To derive a qualitative estimate of the potential environmental benefits that could result
 from implementation of the Initiative's recommendations for strengthened State NPS programs,
 the following steps were taken:

        (1)  An analysis of State section 305(b) Water Body System (WBS) data was performed
        to determine the most prevalent combinations of nonpoint sources and causes  (pollutants)
       associated with impaired and threatened waters,

        (2)  Management measures specified by EPA in its "Management Measures Guidance"
       were assumed to be the "best available management measures" that would be implement-
       ed within 7*/2 years of passage of Clean Water Act amendments,

       (3)  The likelihood that the management measures would measurably improve the water
       quality (within 10 to 20 years) in those threatened and impaired waters was projected for
   5 USDA's Soil Conservation Service has indicated that if implementation is their responsibility, the cost would
range between $211 and $540 million per year to assist the farmers with implementing NPS control measures.

     See also the EPA (1994) background paper "CWA Benefits of Nonpoint Source Controls," January 1994.
These estimates are not net of CZARA benefits and do not account for potential benefits from the implementation
of the Farm Bill of 1990. Therefore, the benefits associated with nonpoint source controls may be somewhat
overestimated.


                                           8

-------
      each combination of water body type, use support status, and prevalent combination of
      nonpoint sources and causes. The 10- to  20-year timeframe was chosen based upon
      extensive experience in NPS programs, as well as on studies that either demonstrate or
      project lag times of 10 or more years before the water quality benefits from pollution
      control efforts can be measured in water bodies;

      (4)  The overall impact of implementation of the best available management measures
      was estimated by summing, by water body type,  the length or area of water body for
      which measurable water quality improvements could be expected,

      (5)  Factors that could either increase or decrease the likelihood of measurable water
      quality improvement were identified,

      (6) All major assumptions made in the analysis were identified and evaluated with regard
      to their impact upon the validity of the analytic results,

      (7)  Selected case studies were identified to gauge the validity of the analytic results and
      to illustrate the significance and specifics of study findings.

Discussion

       The Water Body System (WBS) currently contains data from 1992 for 30 entities. Not
all of the 30 entities  reported data for all  water body types, however.  Some key States for
which data are not reported in the WBS include -California, New York, North Carolina, Florida,
Illinois, Minnesota, Arizona, Colorado, Idaho, and Oregon.

       For this analysis, rivers (28 entities) and lakes (24 entities) were selected.  Very little
data were available for estuaries, coastal waters, and wetlands.  The sources considered in the
analysis  were  agriculture,   silviculture,  construction/urban,   hydromodification/habitat
modification, point sources, and other. Mining, Isind disposal, septic systems, and mannas were
among  the sources included under "other."  Point sources included all point source categories
and subcategories.

        The causes (pollutants)  selected for the  analysis were  nutrients, pesticides, metals,
 siltation, organic enrichment/dissolved oxygen, salinity, flow alteration, other habitat alteration,
 pathogens, oil and grease, suspended solids, and total toxics. The beneficial  uses affected were
 not explored  in  this  analysis, but EPA (1992) has summarized such  information from State
 section 319 assessment reports.  For the 20 states reporting in this analysis, EPA showed that
 wildlife (37 percent  of threatened or impaired waters),  recreation (22 percent),  fishery (15
 percent), agriculture (12 percent), and drinking (9 percent) were the major river uses affected,
 while for 18 states reporting the major lake uses affected were recreation (25 percent), wildlife
 (19 percent), fishery (16 percent), agriculture (13 percent), and  drinking (13 percent).

        To obtain summaries of the most prevalent combinations of sources and pollutants by

-------
  water body type and use support type (fully supported, fully supported but threatened, partially
  supported, not supported), some initial assumptions were made of the most likely candidates for
   prevalent combinations." These assumptions were based upon 305(b) report data and related
  data.  The goal was to account for two-third to three-fourth of the impaired or threatened waters
  for each water body type with information on prevalent combinations.  In  other words  if 75
  percent of the threatened lake acres for the 30 reporting states was accounted for by identifying
  three combinations of sources and pollutants,  then those three combinations would be identified
  as the prevalent combinations," with the remaining 25 percent accounted for by "other."

        Table 5 shows the impaired and threatened river miles for the 28 entities reporting  It
  also shows the share of those miles for which  each of the major sources contributes to the water
  quality problem.  For example, agriculture is a source listed for 79  percent of the partially
  supported river miles.  Table 6 shows the mileage for each of the major sources where it is the
 fiOly listed source.  It is important to note that data in Table 5 are not additive, while data in
 Table 6 are additive.

        While agriculture contributes to the problems in 44,700 of 56,600 partially supported
 river miles (Table 5), only 18,400 of those miles (32 percent)  (Table 6) have agriculture listed
 as the fiQly source.  This finding supports the  approach of looking at prevalent combinations of
 sources and pollutants.  Due to  the very large number  of possible combinations of sources and
 pollutants for each water body, selecting  a subset of combinations for analysis was necessary
 based upon knowledge of the WBS data base.  The combinations of sources shown in Tables 5
 and 6 are those for which a significant percentage of threatened and impaired waters were
 identified. Due to the extremely small numbers resulting for the combinations of sources and
 causes, those data are excluded  from the analysis.

       Table 7  shows the impaired  and  threatened  lake acres for the 24 entities reporting
 excluding the Great Lakes.  It also shows  the  share of those acres for which  each of the major
 sources contributes to the water quality problem.  For example, "urban"  is listed as contributing
 to the water quality problems in 15 percent of lake acres not supporting uses   Data in Table 7
 are not additive. Table 8 shows the acreage for each of the major sources where it is the only
 listed source   Data in Table 8 are additive.  While "urban" contributes to the problems"^
 75,200 of 490,000 lake acres not supporting  uses (Table 7), only 39,300 of those acres  (52
 percent) (Table  8) have urban listed as the only, source. Due to the extremely small numbers
 resulting for the combinations of sources and causes, those data are excluded from the analysis.

       The management measures applied in this analysis are listed in Figure 1. These measures
 are primarily pollution prevention measures, yet the analysis for CWA calls for attention to
 impaired and threatened waters.  The general lack of remediation measures in this list will cause
 a lower expectation of  water quality improvement  than  would otherwise be assumed if
remediation measures were included.  The analysis assumes that all measures were applied as
systems and that whole watersheds were treated.

      The relative likelihood that the management measures would measurably improve the
                                          10

-------
water quality (within 10 to 20 years) of those threatened and impaired waters was projected for
each combination of water body type, use support status, and prevalent combination of nonpoint
sources.  These projections were based upon best professional judgment, as applied in a round-
table discussion of each "prevalent combination" of sources, the management measures that
could be applied to address them, the needs for addressing fully the types of problems identified,
and the type and level of pollution control or treatment provided by the management measures
compared with the needs for addressing the problems.

       The projected likelihood that the management measures will measurably improve water
quality is expressed as "high," "medium," and "low." High likelihood can be interpreted as a
67 to 100 percent chance that measurable water quality improvement will occur within the 10-
to 20-year timeframe, subject to the assumptions specified in this analysis. Medium likelihood
is a 34 to 66 percent chance, and low likelihood is a 0 to 33 percent chance.

       It is important to note  that because the management measures  being  considered are
largely pollution prevention measures, we believe that these measures have a high probability
of protecting waters currently fully supporting beneficial uses.  In other words, we believe that
full implementation of the management measures will maintain full support of uses on 63,500
miles of river (28 entities) and 1.15 million acres of lake (24 entities).  The results of this
analysis for rivers is shown in Table 9, while the lake results are shown in Table  10.

       Summing by water  body type, the data in Tables 9 and 10 provides an overall  estimate
of the likelihood that full implementation of the management measures will result in measurable
water quality improvement.7  Table 11 shows that measurable water quality improvement is
anticipated to occur with high likelihood in 8,300 miles of impaired and threatened river miles
in the 28 entities reporting. This represents 7 percent of the total impaired and threatened river
miles reported by those entities.  Water quality in ;m additional 50,200 miles, or 45 percent, has
a medium likelihood of improving measurably.

       The preceding projections only apply to the 28 states that reported under section 305(b).
Given similarities in use support and major sources,  EPA projected that for all 54 states and
territories, 156,200 river miles, that are impaired or threatened, will show measurable water
quality improvements, as shown in Table 12.  About 10 percent of these river miles are given
a high  likelihood and  roughly 46 percent a medium likelihood. EPA estimates that less than
30,800 threatened and impaired river  miles  are  covered under CZARA and would not be
affected by this provision.

        Table 13 shows that measurable water quality improvements are anticipated to occur with
high likelihood in 225,200  acres of impaired and threatened lake acres in the 24 entities
reporting, excluding  the Great Lakes.  This represents 10  percent  of the total impaired and
    7 For the purposes of this assessment, EPA has defined the term "measurable water quality improvements" to
 generally mean: "statistically significant improvements in measured chemical, physical, and/or biological monitoring
 parameters over a 10- to 20-year period."

                                            11
                                                                                                 _

-------
threatened lake acres reported by those entities.  Water quality in an additional 1.15 million
acres, or 53 percent, have a medium likelihood of improving measurably. Given similarities in
use support and major sources, EPA projected that for all 54 states and territories, 7.1 million
lake acres, that are impaired or threatened, will show measurable water quality improvements,
as shown in Table 14.  About 10 percent of these lake acres are given a high likelihood of
improvement and about 58 percent are given a medium likelihood.  The total lake acreage that
may benefit from the implementation of CZARA, which  is oriented towards  coastal  water
bodies, will be nominal except in Florida and Louisiana.  (The Great Lakes were not included
in either projection.)

      Many factors and assumptions were identified that could either increase or decrease the
likelihood of measurable water quality improvements.  These include:

  •   Management measures are generally pollution prevention measures. If remedial activities
      accompany the measures, then the likelihood of water  quality improvement should
      increase.

  •   Rapidly flowing systems and systems with short hydrologic retention times have a greater
      chance of  achieving water quality improvement in 10- to 20-years, while slow-moving
      systems and systems  with long  hydrologic retention  times have  a lesser chance of
      achieving water quality improvement.

  •   The intensity of land-based activity will affect the likelihood of achieving water quality
      improvement.   For example,  a rapidly urbanizing area  will result in much  more
      construction and pollutant loading than a slowly  urbanizing area  where the  same
      measures are applied.

  •   Rapid changes in pollutant loadings to lakes may result in changes at the sediment-water
      interface that cause a short-term increase in flux of pollutants (e.g., phosphorus) from
      bottom sediments.   This may cause temporary  delays  in achieving water  quality
      improvements, and sometimes temporary decreases in water quality.

  •   Management measures are fully  applied within 2  to 3 years.   This  includes full
      application of measures such as in-stream and riparian habitat restoration, and  other
      measures for which states are given considerable latitude.

  •   Management measures are well designed, implemented, operated, and maintained.

  •   Point source controls  will be needed in conjunction with NPS controls where both
      sources exist,  so these situations could not be evaluated in this analysis.

  •   The analysis assumed  a baseline of low to nonexistent watershed management.  This
      results in an assumption of greater possible water quality improvement than would be
      possible if some management existed.  To partially adjust for this, the analysis employed
                                          12

-------
       conservative assumptions of water quality improvement resulting from management
       measure implementation.

  •    Each source identified as a  "prevalent combination"  was considered to be a typical
       example rather than an extreme example.  In other words, the treatment needs were
       considered to be "average."

  •    Each water body problem was assumed to be independent of the other water bodies.

  •    Water bodies were assumed  to be "normal" (e.g., second order stream) rather than
       "special" (e.g., ephemeral stream).

       Selected case studies were identified to gauge the validity of the analytic results, and to
illustrate the significance and specifics of study findings. These can be found in Appendix A.
                                         13

-------
4.0    Storm Water

       EPA's current Phase I storm water program requires NPDES permits  of cities and
counties with municipal separate storm sewer systems (MS4s) serving populations of 100,000
or more and "storm water discharges associated with significant industrial activity." The Phase
II program, currently suspended due to a Congressional moratorium, could require permits for
all private sources of storm water (commercial, industrial, retail, and institutional) and all MS4s
serving all populations that have the potential to affect water quality.  In the Initiative, EPA has
addressed the potentially high costs of the Phase II program while still providing protection from
private sources and additional MS4s.

       The "worse case" scenario for storm water permitting reflects the most inclusive option
of all potential options that EPA would consider in proposing rules for the types of facilities
covered under Phase II. If EPA were to propose regulations for permitting Phase II facilities,
EPA may propose to cover only a portion of these facilities, based on consideration of costs
incurred and environmental benefits gained.  EPA could propose regulations covering the same
facilities to the same extent as suggested in the Initiative.

       The Initiative's Phase II program will focus on system-wide permits for MS4s in Census-
designated urbanized areas~i.e., areas with a population of 50,000 or more  and a population
density of 1,000 persons per square mile. The Census Bureau has identified 396 such urbanized
areas  nationwide.   Phase II MS4s  will be required to implement  storm water management
programs that are subject to a "maximum extent practicable" (MEP) standard.  These programs
will, at a minimum,  address:  (1) nonstorm  water  discharges to their  systems  (i.e., illicit
connections)  and  (2)  storm  water runoff from  growth  and development and  significant
redevelopment activities (including discharges from construction of less than 5 acres) and, where
appropriate, those Phase II sources causing water quality impairment.

       Where the NPDES  authority deems it necessary, MS4s in the 138 urbanized areas
associated with a Phase I permitted MS4 may be  required to have a more comprehensive storm
water  management program  (consistent with  the  Phase I storm water requirements).  The
comprehensive  storm  water  management  programs  would cover Phase II light industrial,
commercial, retail, and institutional storm water sources under a municipality's storm water
permit.  The NPDES  program would  not cover  Phase II sources not addressed through a
municipal program.  Such discharges could be addressed by the NPS program if they  were a
targeted source.

       4.1   Private Sources

       Under a stringent interpretation of the CWA, the current Phase I program is estimated
to cost industrial permittees $3.99 billion per  year, while Phase II under a similarly stringent
interpretation could cost as much as $16.23 billion in annual costs.
                                          14

-------
ranges   hen     ** "fT**0* * estimatinS *e potential costs, EPA has developed


           Sws: C°nSlderaWy' imp°sin* cosf:s of b*ween $0.34 billion and $1.67 billion
  10,000 facilities x $22,340/facility
  28,000 facilities x $34,700/facility

  96,000 facilities x $630/facility
  269,000 facilities x $l,885/facility

  100,000 sites x $630/site
  100,000 sites x $l,885/site

     TOTAL
 Low
 $0.22 billion
$0.06 billion


$0.06 billion


$0.34 billion
 High

 $0.97 billion


 $0.51 billion


 $0.19 billion

$1.67 billion
                     COSt f°r m           --                            ».22
                                                 sw^^

                         '


                                      15

-------
that  the  moratorium will expire, the Initiative will avoid costs (or yield a cost savings) of
between $14.6 billion and $15.9 billion.










 in Table 21.
        4.2    Municipalities









  between $1.8 and $2.7 billion per year.
                                                                              stom Wattt penm'
    Applications" (EPA, 1993c).
                                                16

-------
a comprehensive plan above the cost of addressing growth and development and illicit discharges
will be in the range of $8.58 and $13.28 per capita.  The total cost of the comprehensive
coverage will vary from a low of $0.05 billion to a high of $0.24 billion.

       EPA identified 29 million people in another 258 UAs who will be affected by the Phase
II provisions. The cost of compliance will vary from $15.33 per capita to $23.72 per capita.
The total cost of this coverage will be in the range of $0.44 billion and $0.69 billion.  The final
element of this cost  on municipalities is the cost of addressing private sources and industrial
look-a-likes that impact water quality in areas without the comprehensive program and in areas
with combine sewers.   At a per capita cost of $2.00,  EPA estimates that about 75.7 million
people will incur $0.15 billion. At a per capita, cost of $5.00, the upper-end cost would be
$0.38 billion.
                                               Low
  25.3 million population x $15.33 per capita    $0.39 billion
  25.3 million population x $23.72 per capita
  6.33 million population x $8.58 per capita
  17.7 million population x $13.28 per capita
$0.05 billion
  29.0 million population x $15.33 per capita    $0.44 billion
  29.0 million population x $23.72 per capita
  75.7 million population x $2.00 per capita
  75.7 million population x $5.00 per capita

       TOTAL
$0.15 billion
$1.03 billion
High

$0.60 billion


$0.24 billion


$0.69 billion


$0.38 billion

$1.91 billion
       The total cost to the municipalities of the proposed Phase II requirements is between
$1.03 billion and $1.91 billion, as shown in Table 20.

       Compared with the cost of Phase II requirements under a stringent interpretation of the
current law, total savings to municipalities will be between $755 million and $850 million per
year.

       4.3    State Water Programs

       The impacts of the Phase II storm water provisions on states have not been estimated but
are expected to be minimal.

       4.4    Federal Agencies

       Additional costs of the storm water provisions on federal agencies will total $19 million
per year.  EPA will account for $2 million per year of this cost, and DOI will account for $17
                                           17

-------
million per year.

       4.5    Benefits9

       The benefits of storm water control as proposed in the Initiative are based on numerous
case studies and are summarized as follows:

       *•      75 to 80  percent  reduced loadings in urbanized areas prior to and  during
              development,

       >      15 to 25 percent reduced loadings in areas already developed,

       >      Greater  environmental protection at lower cost,

       >      Improved  water resource quality,  habitat, and aquatic life; reduced flooding;
              improved  recreational opportunities; increased commercial fishing; improved
              human health; and  increased employment.

(Note that more cost-effective and institutionally feasible prevention and management methods
are available for new development than for areas that have already been developed.)

       Case Studies10

       Bellevue, Washington  (see longer summary in Appendix B)

       Bellevue has a population of nearly 87,000 and covers a 30-square mile area that contains
five lakes and over 50  miles of open streams. The city established a storm water utility in 1974
to maintain a hydrologic balance, prevent property damage, and protect water quality.

       The city requires newly developing areas to include on-site storm water management that
provides protection for 24-hour, 100-year storm events.

       Examples of program benefits:

              Flood control.   One of the  most successful  aspects of the program is  flood
              control, which relies on eight remote-controlled regional detention basins along
              major stream corridors to monitor rainfall, stream flow, and water levels.  This
              helps ensure that flood gates control peak flows. Small detention basins reduce
              peak flow rates up to 60 percent, providing flood and stream-bank erosion control
              and protecting stream-side property.
    9 See also the EPA (1994e) background paper "CWA Benefits of Storm Water Controls," January 1994.

    10 Costs for these case studies were not available and hence are not included here.

                                           18

-------
             Reduced property damage.  As a result of storm water controls over the previous
             10 years, property damages were avoided during a 100-year storm in January
             1986.

             Reduced pollutant loadings.  Runoff concentrations of lead and total solids were
             reduced by 10 to 25 percent through biannual cleaning of storm drainage inlet
             pumps and catch basins; oxygen demanding substances,  nutrients,  and zinc
             concentrations were reduced by 5 to 10 percent.  Conventional street-sweeping
             operations reduced toxic loadings by 5 to 10 percent.  Installation and mainte-
             nance of oil/water separators reduced floatables in the drainage system.

             Reduced illegal dumping. Dumping of motor oil and debris hi storm drains was
             significantly reduced through increasing public awareness of storm water issues
             and  volunteer stenciling of storm drains.   A recent survey indicates that  85
             percent of area residents dispose of used oil at a recycling facility.

             Increased recreational opportunities.  Clean-up  of Mercer Slough (a 325-acre
             wetland) along with stream and wildlife enhancement of the park resulted in
             increased canoeing on the slough and increased visitation to the park's trails.

       Murray City, Utah

       Murray City (population 31,000) worked with the  Utah Department of Transportation
(DOT) to develop a storm water control system for runoff from a 4,.5-mile stretch of highway
in conjunction with the construction of an 18-hole, 135-acre municipal golf course.

       Storm water runoff from the highway and subsurface waters  is collected and routed
through a series  of streams and wetlands into four ponds on the golf course.

       Examples of program benefits:

             Reduction in pollutant loadings.  The pond system  removes approximately 90
             percent of the sediment, oil and grease, and dissolved materials from the highway
             runoff.

             Flood control.  The system successfully handled the runoff from two 25-year
              storms.

              Savings in irrigation water costs.  The detention ponds provide 7 acres of flood
              retention area and created nearly 11 acres of wetlands.  The ponds also provide
              water to irrigate the golf course, which saves nearly $80,000 per year in watering
              costs.

              Savings in highway construction costs. Because runoff was diverted to irrigate
                                           19

-------
               the golf course, DOT saved $300,000 in land acquisition and storm water piping
               costs by eliminating the need to construct a separate storm water discharge system
               for the highway.

        Orlando, Florida

        The city of Orlando (population 160,000) receives over 50 inches of rain annually, over
 half of which converts to storm water runoff and flows into the city's 83 lakes.  One example
 of a project to manage storm water is the creation of the Greenwood Urban Wetland, which
 consists of several ponds in a series.

       Examples of program  benefits:

              Increased property values.  Overall, whenever Orlando constructs a storm water
              control lake, property values in that area increase.

              A savings was realized in construction of the Greenwood Urban Storm Water
              Control Wetland with the sale of fill dirt that was excavated ($5/cubic yard).

              Creation of a natural park. The Greenwood Urban Wetland  created a natural
              park atmosphere (with footbridges, walking paths, picnic areas,  and opportunities
              for observing wetland wildlife) in an urbanized area.

              Irrigation and drinking water supply. Cleansed storm water is used to irrigate the
              upland areas of the park, which conserves the drinking water supply.

       Santa Clara Valley, California

       Santa Clara Valley has a municipal storm water  permit covering  15  co-permittees
(14 municipal entities and one water  control  district).   Three  of  the municipalities have
populations over 100,000, four are between 50,000 and 100,000, and seven are less than 50,000.

       Transportation  activities have been identified as potentially the most significant source
of storm water pollutants.  Copper and zinc have been identified as significant contaminants in
the storm water runoff into south San Francisco Bay. These metal are carried by  suspended
particles. Brake pad dust is believed to be a major source of the copper.

       Examples of program benefits:

             Significant reduction in copper loadings. Street sweeping activities clean 19,000
             miles per month and have prevented 2,500 pounds of copper and  46,000 cubic
             yards of material throughout the area from entering storm sewers.

       ~     Reduction in floatables.  Cleaning 34,000 catch basins has removed 1,000 cubic
                                           20

-------
             yards of material.  Inspection and cleaning of 160 miles of conveyances has
             removed 400 cubic yards of material.

             Identification of illegal dumping activities. The co-permittees identified 867 cases
             of illegal dumping, of which 700 have been resolved.

       Tulsa, Oklahoma

       The city of Tulsa (population 367,000) has been recognized as having an effective storm
water management program.  EPA recently issued a draft municipal storm water permit for
Tulsa.

       Discharges from Tulsa's storm  sewer collection system were identified as a source of
pollutant loadings in the Zinc Lake portion of the Arkansas River. The storm sewer's discharges
showed a high concentration of bacteria.

       Examples of program benefits:

              Removal of suspended solids. Msa estimates that its construction site storm
              water controls average 70 percent effectiveness in removing total suspended solids
              from storm water runoff.  In addition, the city estimates that its street sweeping
              and structural  operation and maintenance reduce suspended solids by up to 50
              percent; metals by up to 10 percent; total solids and lead by 10 to 25 percent; and
              oxygen demanding substances, nutrients, and zinc by 5 to 10 percent.

              Improved Water Quality in the  Arkansas River.  The city identified 35 illicit
              storm sewer connections drained into Zinc Lake and the Arkansas River. Tulsa
              removed these discharges from  the storm  sewer system and  states that water
              resource quality has improved as a result.
                                            21

-------
  5.0    Combined Sewer Overflows

         Combined sewer overflows (CSOs) occur in sewer systems that combine sanitary sewage
  and surface runoff. When storms occur, the combined sewer system (CSS) capacity is exceeded
  and the mixture of sewage, untreated industrial and commercial wastes, storm water runoff and
  other waste in the system is discharged to surface waters. Human and animal waste, pollutants
  from industrial and commercial sources, trash, and oil and grease are discharged.

        EPA's CSO  Control Policy (EPA,  1993) establishes a national  framework and  clear
  expectations for the control of CSOs.  The CSO  Policy is largely the result of a successful
  negotiations with key CSO stakeholders, including municipal groups, environmental groups and
  states.  It addresses the unique characteristics of CSO controls and balances considerations of
  the site-specific nature of CSOs and their environmental impacts.  The Policy also provides for
  an evaluation of the cost effectiveness of CSO controls; consideration of a community's ability
  !?cS?y    CS° abatement' and other factors necessary for developing flexible and cost effective
  CSO control measures.  The Initiative would clarify EPA's authority to implement the  CSO
  Policy and would provide legislative reference in the CWA for this policy.

        5.1    Private Sources

        The impacts of the CSO provisions on private sources have not been estimated but are
 expected to be minimal.

        5.2   Municipalities

        EPA's 1992 CSO Needs Survey estimates that the national costs of CSO control with 85
 percent capture and primary clarification is $41.2  billion in 1992 dollars (Metcalf & Eddy
 1993).    EPA estimates that  these costs will be borne in  years 3  to  15 following CWA
 reauthorization (or in some cases, over  longer periods).  Annual operating  and maintenance
 (O&M) expenditures associated with these capital expenditures are estimated at $300 million per
 year.  Annual costs for CSO abatement are thus $3.45 billion per year (see Table 19) derived
 by dividing the total CSO capital needs by 13 years and adding the O&M costs  ($41.2 billion
 •s- 13 years + $300 million  = $3.45 billion).  EPA plans to implement the Policy and hence
 no incremental costs are shown in Table  20.

       During the negotiations, CSO stakeholders considered a range of controls and alternatives
 that achieved various  degrees of environmental and public health benefits  at different national
 costs. Figure 2 and Table 15 are examples of the data considered and the relationships that exist
 between controls and costs. The negotiations focused on the reduction of raw  sewage overflow
 events rather than on the reduction of pounds of pollutants. Raw sewage overflows were viewed


   " CSO "control" is defined based on the goal of "... the elimination or capture of 85 percent by volume of
the combined sewage collected in the combined sewer system during precipitation events on a system-wide average
D3S1S.. • (JDJrAj 1993).
                                          22

-------
as the key concern because they result in immediate violations of water quality'Standards and
created  immediate public health concerns  for the downstream  beaches, shellfish beds and
drinking water intakes.  With this as a guiding principle, stakeholders focused on the extentof
the reductions of CSO overflow events.  Four to  six overflow events, equivalent to 85 percent
capture and primary clarification, was determined to be an appropnate target of control, m the
absence of clear date that show the level of control necessary to meet water quality standards.
A municipality may demonstrate that another level of control is adequate to meet water quality
standards.

        Full implementation of the CSO requirements, according to one interpretation that is not
shared  by EPA, could  cost as much as $14.14 billion per year (EPA, 1994d)  base<1 on _an
assumption of 85 percent capture with secondary treatment, as shown in Table 22. The Initiative
Lproposing to codify the CSO control strategy  that could  potential save municipalities about
 $10.7 billion annually in avoided costs.

        5.3   State Water Programs

        The impacts of  the CSO provisions on states have not been estimated but are expected
 to be minimal.

        5.4    Federal Agencies

        The additional impacts of the CSO provisions on federal agencies have not been estimated
 but are expected to be minimal.

        5.5    Benefits

        The benefits of the Initiative's CSO provisions will be  to reduce  the discharge of
  untreated sewage and pollutant loadings associated with CSSs.  In the affected areas  this will
  have potentially major economic and environmental impacts, which are discussed below.

        Reductions in Volumes of Untreated Sewage and Pollutant Loadings Reduction from
        CSOs

        On  average, CSSs experience 50 to 80 overflow events per year. The number will be
  reduced to  approximately 3 to 4 events. This will have major implications for the water quality
  of the receiving waters, including:

         *      Reduce the number of water quality standards (WQS) violations for each system
                from 100 to 200 days per year to no more  than  10 to 20 days per year.
         *     Reduce CSO discharges from 1,200 billion gallons per year to 180 billion gallons
                per year.

          ^     Reduce annual TSS discharges from 3.7 billion pounds to 1.29 billion pounds.


                                             23

-------
  the
               Reduce annual BOD discharges from 1,150 million pounds to 635 million pounds.  "

               Reduce by 35  to  65 percent  the  current annual amounts of the following
               discharges: 19 imlhon pounds of ortho phosphate (PO4-P), 95 million pounds of

               SSL?I *gr; 18^ UlonP°und!l°f metals (zinc' c°PPer> cadmi™> cooler, lead,
               nickel), and 4 million pounds of toxic volatile organics.

                              Regarding Compliance with CWA  and  Water Quality
                                                            uses because of cso affects
              503 square miles of estuaries
              132 shore-miles of coastal waters
              93 shore-miles of impaired Great Lakes
              21,360 lake-acres in fresh lakes
              5,163 river-miles


      ^L^T^011- W^ streamline *e permit writing and water quality standards
      s>es, oener aetine the criteria appropriate to support the designated uses of CSO
waters, and result in compliance with applicable state water quality standards.

      Shellfishing Restrictions

      In 1990, CSOs contributed to prohibitions, conditions, or restrictions on 597 (
or 9.4 percent of the total harvest-limited acreage.   Sixteen percent of the limi '

^^2^^^^^^^^  CSOS'  Substantial reduction in

      Fish Kills
                                                                               acres
              Von8*! ^"^ Water Onality  Inventory, 38 states reported 996 fish Mil
rfl     nl 1  •' .^enty-f°UT of ^ states ^Ported the number of fish killed: a total
of 36 rmllion.  Of the incidents reported, 605 were caused by conventional pollutants (primarily
oxygen-demanding substances),  while 135  were caused by toxic pollutes.  SixtSn^ates
reported municipal facilities, which may include CSOs, as a source of fish Mils ThTconteols

^SS^S^^'vca^ wm signiflcantly eliminate discharges rf«St ^S
pollutants (BOD) and toxics in concentrations that deplete dissolved oxygen concentrations below
those required to support fish resulting in substantial reductions in Fish Advisories.

      Beach Closures

      According to NRDC, 1,592 days of beach closures or advisories were issued in 1990,
                                        24

-------
2,008 days in 1991, and 2,619 in 1992.  CSOs were implicated as an important contributor to
those beach closures.

       The presence of plastics and other floatable waste or debris, which in some cases can be
traced to  CSO  may also prompt health authorities  to  close public beaches  or issue beach
Stories.  The floltabJ problem  has  become particularly  acute m  some urban  areas,
particularly in the vicinity of New York City.

       Flooding

       Most cities'  CSSs were built over 40 years ago. New developments and greased flow
 often resuU in sewer surcharge and basements flooding during wet weather,   I, ^add^n to
       tv  damage related to the flooding, clean-up poses senous heath nsks.   CSO abatement
       wnS help eliminate basement flooding.  This has been demonstrated m the City of
 Portland, Oregon.

       Avoided Drinking Water Treatment Costs

       Tinder the CSO Policv  the discharge of undisinfected CSOs to  surface waters used as
 public d^Mng watefsuppIS wm be dranfatically reduced, reducing pathogens and bacteria to
 F^that SLdequaSy treated by water supply facilities and resulting in savings in the cost
 of drinking water disinfection and a reduction in human health nsks.,

        Aesthetic Improvements

        CSO abatement efforts will eliminate the discharge of condoms, tampon applicators, and
  other sewaee-related floatables that  degrade the aesthetic  quality  of  receiving waters  limi
  r^SLefdTmage property values, and threaten wildlife (by ingestion of or entanglement

  in plastic debris).

  Other Effects

         Jobs Supported

         The estimated number of direct and  indirect jobs supported by a $1 billion investment
  in watered w^ater infrastructure is  16,500, with an additional 16 ;500 ^duc^'
            nationwide.  According to these  estimates, implementation  of the CSO Policy
                      direct and indirect jobs and another 57,000 induced jobs per year.
         Public Access

         In concert with the construction of CSO controls, Columbus  Georgia,  cleaned up a
   hazardous waste  site,  refurbished the shoreline of the Chattahoochee  River   and bu^ ^ a
   b^cle/walking path along the River,  thus greatly enhancing public access.  CSO abatement
                                             25

-------
efforts in many other cities will create similar opportunities for significant indirect benefits.
                                         26

-------
6.0    Toxics Controls

       The Initiative provides additional authority to EPA to limit releases of the most toxic and
bioaccumulative pollutants.

       6.1    Private Sources

       Currently EPA's primary pollution control efforts are focused on point source discharges
to water.  For  many pollutants, other sources  are the largest contributors of contaminants.
Mercury, for example, one of a limited number of highly toxic and bioaccumulative pollutants,
is present in surface water largely from atmospheric deposition. Restricting or banning the point
source discharge of toxic pollutants may not be the most cost effective approach.  A cross-media
approach allows the Agency the flexibility to select the most cost-effective controls.

       Due to our inability to predict which pollutants might be impacted and what costs might
be incurred by  dischargers, EPA has  not estimated the costs of the Initiative's toxics control
provision.  The toxics ban/restriction provision  would affect private sources, leading industry
to use pollution prevention measures, in-plant controls,  and/or new technologies.  Restrictions
or bans  could be costly.  For example, industry estimates  the cost of eliminating dioxin from
bleached kraft pulp production at $1.3 billion annually (Phillips et al.,  1993).  Setting effluent
 standards at the detection limit is estimated to cost about $140 million annually (Nicoll,  1994).
However, other sources of dioxin may be more cost effective to control.  This provision will
allow the review of all sources in selecting an appropriate  source of control.

       6.2   Municipalities

       The impacts of the toxics provision on municipal sources have not been estimated but are
 expected to be minimal.

       6.3   State Water Programs

       The impacts of the toxics provisions on states have not been estimated but are expected
 to be minimal.

        6.4   Federal Agencies

        The toxics provisions will impose additional administrative costs  on EPA,  and further
 compliance costs on agencies such as USDA,  DOI, DOD, and NOAA.  EPA will  not incur
 incremental costs. Compliance by other agencies, will impose estimated annual costs of between
 $66 million  and  $105 million.  Table  4 summarizes the impacts of these provisions on the
 federal  agencies.
                                            27

-------
       6.5    Benefits12

       The  Initiative's  toxics provisions provide EPA with further authority  to restrict or
eliminate discharges of the most highly toxic and/or bioaccumulative pollutants.  Reductions in
the magnitude of such releases will have potential benefits on human health and the environment.
Several categories of benefits are discussed below.

       Reduced Human Health and Aquatic Life Impacts

       >      Toxics (bioaccumulative pollutants in particular) are linked with  birth defects,
              cancer, neurological disorders,  reduced IQ, heart disease, and kidney ailments.

       >      Many aquatic organisms are more sensitive than humans to toxics.

       »>      Toxics can alter species composition/diversity,  increase susceptibility to disease,
              interfere with reproduction, reduce viability of young, and increase mortality.

       >•      Some pollutants are extremely harmful in small quantities and/or build up in the
              food  chain to produce adverse  and long-term  effects  to human health and the
              environment. This is recognized in the Great Lakes, where the United States has
              formed an international joint commission with Canada to develop  a virtual
             elimination  strategy for  persistent toxic  substances.   In  addition,  EPA  has
             proposed the Great Lakes Water Quality Initiative, which requires more stringent
             water quality standards for persistent bioaccumulative pollutants.

       >     Bioaccumulative pollutants  can damage  ecosystems  by  directly eliminating
             sensitive  species or indirectly  causing increased  incidence of disease in  the
             remaining species.

       >     Some bioaccumulative pollutants may persist in the environment for  decades,
             posing a  continuing threat to  humans,  aquatic organisms, birds,  and other
             wildlife.

      Decreased Fish Consumption Advisories

      *•     Some 1,280 water bodies have fish consumption advisories or bans in place to
             protect human health,

      >      Most  of  the total  number of  advisories are in  Minnesota and Wisconsin.
             However,  no uniform approach exists among states  for issuing advisories,
   12
     See also the EPA (1994f) background paper "CWA Benefits of Toxics Controls," January 1994.

                                         28

-------
      *      Of the advisories,  60 percent are  for mercury,  21 percent for PCBs, and  6
             percent for chlordane.

      Decreased Amount of Contaminated Sediments

      >      The U.S. Army Corps of Engineers dredges from 300 to 400 million cubic yards
             annually;  based on Corps data for  19 districts (out of 30), almost 10 percent of
             the dredged material required special handling because of toxics,

      *      Costs of special handling are highly variable, from as little as $ 10 per cubic yard
             to more than $100 per  cubic yard (total cost of special handling equals $160
             million to $1.6 billion),

      *      Costs of normal handling is $1 to $10 per cubic yard (total cost if toxics are not
             present  equals $16 million to $160 million),

      >      Total estimated remediation  costs of  PCB-contammated sediments  at  five
             Superfund sites ranged from $93 million to $520 million ($1991).

Case studies illustrating  the potential benefits of toxics reduction can be found in Appendix C.
                                           29

-------
 7.0    Comprehensive Watershed Management

        The Initiative provides support for the "watershed management approach," a geographic-
 based strategy for addressing water quality problems.  Under these provisions, states would
 identify and prioritize watersheds,  designate watershed  management entities, and oversee the
 development of watershed management plans.   EPA would provide guidance to the states and
 to watershed management entities, and would approve state watershed  programs.   As an
 incentive to participate in the watershed approach, states would be eligible to consolidate several
 existing grants (SRF excluded) into a multipurpose grant.

       7.1    Private Sources

       The impacts of the watershed management  provisions  will be felt when  watershed
 management plans are developed and the sources contributing to impairment are identified. The
 plans will define measures necessary to ensure further progress within the economic capability
 of the sources and will include such pollution load reduction allocations  for point and nonpoint
 sources as are necessary to ensure further progress.

       Because of the number of steps that must occur before affected parties would be required
 to undertake compliance actions, estimating the potential scope of these  impacts is impossible.
 For a particular impaired  watershed, one can envision a plan that identifies point or nonpoint
 sources as contributors to impairment and imposes upon them economically achievable measures
 to reduce discharges and improve water quality.  Until such plans are developed, however, the
 potential overall costs of such requirements cannot be estimated.

       7.2   Municipalities

       In some watersheds, municipal sources (e.g., sewage treatment facility operation, road
 salting, municipal construction, landscaping) may be important contributors  to  water quality
 problems.  Watershed management plans may identify these sources and propose new controls
 or provide new incentives to reduce their pollutant contribution.  As indicated under the private
 sources section above, however, the impacts on municipalities will be felt only after watersheds
 are assessed, problems are identified, and plans are developed and approved.  The contingent
 nature of any changes that would be required makes it difficult to estimate the potential impacts
 at this time.

       7.3   State Water Programs

       Impacts of the comprehensive watershed management provisions on state water programs
 are estimated at $82 million per year (EPA, 1993f).  These costs are attributable to the new
responsibilities states will have for identifying watersheds, designating watershed management
entities,  overseeing  the development of watershed  management plans, and  pursuing  and
administering any funding  for watershed activities.
                                          30

-------
       7.4   Federal Agencies

       Impacts of the comprehensive watershed management provisions on federal agencies are
combined with the costs of NFS control and are shown in Table 4 to total between $329 and
$750 million per year.

       7.5   Benefits13

       The benefits of the watershed approach are best characterized as including cost savings
due to administrative efficiency and the use of cost-effective control strategies  that take  all
sources into account.

       >      A watershed approach allows the development of controls that enable ecosystems
              to function properly and recreational opportunities  (e.g., fishing,  boating, and
              enhanced tourist visitation) to increase.

       >      A watershed approach, particularly when used in conjunction with technical tools
              such  as  Total Maximum  Daily Load  (TMDL),   allows  development and
              implementation of alternative, cost effective approaches for reducing adverse
              impacts on water bodies.

       >      A watershed approach can go beyond traditional regulatory relationships and
              techniques to solve environmental problems.  Stakeholder involvement improve-
              ments chances of success. Experience has shown the voluntary participation of
              interested parties at the watershed level can yield more gains than a traditional
              top-down regulatory approach. Watershed management can facilitate local actions
              and decisions such as changes in zoning laws that cannot be made  effectively at
              the federal or state level.

       Numerous ongoing watershed projects exist across the country. Below are summaries
 of some of the notable projects and their successes:

        +     The   Boulder  Creek,  Colorado, Enhancement  Project,  following a parallel
              approach to the TMDL process, addressed elevated in-stream pH, temperature,
              and ammonia concentrations, as well as reductions in. fish and macroinvertebrate
              species density and diversity.  A partnership of local, state, and federal entities
              crafted a holistic strategy  that combined  a point  source upgrade at the local
              wastewater treatment plant  (WWTP),  with agricultural NPS best management
              practices and riparian zone and in-stream habitat restoration.  The total cost of
              restoring approximately 5 stream miles  is currently estimated at  $1.3 to $1.4
     13 See also the EPA (1994g) background paper "CWA Benefits of a Watershed Protection Approach," January
 1994.

                                            31

-------
 million, far less than relying on wastewater treatment plant upgrades alone, which
 was estimated at $23 million.  Restoration of the physical condition of the creek
 and its riparian zone has enhanced fish habitat, improved aesthetics, made the
 creek more appealing and useful to the community, and resulted in attainment of
 water quality goals.  Restoration of the creek, as part of a broader  watershed
 improvement effort,  has also increased recreational  benefits  through  the
 development of bicycle pathways and educational displays.

 The Patuxent River watershed, which drains into the Chesapeake Bay,  is situated
 between Baltimore and Washington, a rapidly growing area that has experienced
 large increases in population over the past decade.  By the 1970s the Patuxent had
 become one of the most nutrient-enriched systems in the Bay  region,  with
 associated dissolved oxygen and water clarity problems.   A plan was  developed
 in the early 1980s, with the involvement of state agencies, elected officials, local
 governments, and  scientists, to reduce point and NPS loadings of nitrogen and
 phosphorus. Total capital costs for plant improvements from 1980 to 1992 were
 $196 million.

 Nutrient Loads from the WWTPs have been reduced substantially in the Patuxent
 Watershed since 1984.  Specifically, phosphorus loads have been reduced by
 approximately 75  percent through chemical addition methods  and a phosphate
 detergent ban  instituted  in  1986.    Nitrogen loads have been reduced  by
 approximately 35  percent annually and by about 50  percent during  warmer
 months through implementation of Biological Nutrient Removal (BNR) methods.
 The Patuxent River Estuary is already showing positive responses. In the Upper
 estuary, total nitrogen concentrations have  significantly declined since 1984,
 ranging from about 40 percent in the upper tidal fresh water region to about 30
 percent in the Oligohaline (slightly  brackish)  region  of the estuary. Total
 phosphorus concentrations have declined significantly throughout  the estuary,
 ranging from 70 percent in the upper tidal fresh water region to about 20 percent
 in the Mesohalic (brackish water) region.

 In the Tar Pamlico Basin, North Carolina, a nutrient trading program  was
 developed by a coalition of dischargers, environmental groups, and the North
 Carolina Department of  Environmental Management.   The  program allows
 dischargers to pay for the development and implementation of agricultural best
 management practices, which reduce nutrients  by 200,000 kg/yr.  When  fully
 implemented, the trading program will achieve the state's nutrient reduction goals
 and address NPS loadings while also reducing the economic burden to municipal
 dischargers.  In addition, the program is flexible, allowing discharges to trade
reduction debits and credits among themselves,  as long as the loading  standards
for the basin are met.  The trading program is cost effective, with an  estimated
cost  of $11.8 million for achieving the state's  nutrient  reduction goal using
agricultural best management practices alone.
                             32

-------
A pollution reduction trading strategy was designed for the Dillon Reservoir,
Colorado, by a committee of local, state, and  EPA representatives  to  control
increased phosphorus loading from urban nonpoint sources, and to accommodate
future development. The trading strategy provides an innovative solution for
controlling phosphorus  loading while still meeting water quality goals.  The
trading strategy allows wastewater treatment plants to use low-tech, inexpensive
NFS  controls for phosphorus removal in lieu of costly point source controls.
Total cost savings are estimated to be $1.33 million.

New  York City is seeking an alternative to installing filtration on its Catskill and
Delaware drinking water supplies.  By implementing a series of water quality,
operational, and watershed protection criteria, the City anticipates being able to
ensure drinking water quality.  The City estimates that the cost of implementing
the criteria would total $1 billion, while the cost of filtration would total $5 to $6
billion.  Although New  York City has the authority to mandate land use changes,
it has elected to pursue  a collaborative effort with other watershed communities.
The plan for watershed protection  would include $120 million in cost share to
communities and farmers for both point and NFS controls in  addition to land
purchases.  Specific land use plans are to be initiated by watershed communities
and farmers, and evaluated to make sure that pollution prevention goals are
reached.
                               33

-------
 8.0   Permit Discharge Fees

       The Initiative recommends the collection of permit fees to partially offset the cost of
 operating the National Pollutant Discharge Elimination System (NPDES), pretreatment, and
 sludge programs. For States authorized to administer these programs, the Initiative recommends
 collection of fees to cover these programs, and the portion of other State water quality programs
 that support these programs, to the extent that these programs are not currently funded by other
 sources such as State appropriations or current State permit fees.  For the states where EPA is
 the regulatory authority, the Initiative recommends collection of fees to cover the full cost of the
 NPDES, pretreatment, and sludge programs.

       EPA has calculated that States are currently spending $498 million per  year to operate
 State water quality  programs (EPA, 1993f).   Of this cost,  $250 million per  year is  for
 administering the NPDES and pretreatment point source programs (no State has yet received
 authorization to administer the sludge program), and $70 million per year is for nonpoint source
 control program.  Li addition, States are  spending $165 million per year for the standards,
 monitoring, and  watershed programs.   Because these programs support  both the point and
 nonpoint source programs, EPA attributes  80 percent of the cost of these programs to support
 the NPDES and  pretreatment programs, with  the remaining 20 percent to support nonpoint
 source programs.

       EPA projects that the Initiative would add $416 million per year to the existing cost for
 all States to operate  their existing programs.  Of this total cost, $179 million  per year is  for
 operation of the NPDES  and pretreatment programs in the authorized States and $218 million
 per year for the standards, monitoring, and watershed programs in all States.   Since only 40
 States and Territories are authorized out of a potential total of 57 and only 80 percent of the
 standards, monitoring, and watershed programs can be attributed to point source controls, permit
 fees would only need to recover $122 million per year  (80 percent of 70 percent of States &
 Territories of $218 million per year). The total additional fees collected by States would be the
 sum of these two components, or a total of $301 million per year.

       In the 17 States and Territories where EPA administers the NPDES, pretreatment, and
 sludge programs,  the cost to EPA of operating  these programs is estimated as $83 million per
 year.  The total  fees to  be collected under the Initiative is the sum of the EPA and State
 collections, or a total of $384 million per year.

       8.1    Private Sources

       EPA estimates the total permit fees required of private sources to be $290 million per
year.  These sources represent roughly 75.6 percent  of all the facilities permitted under the
NPDES program. The total fee is based on 75.6%  of the total of the fees collected by EPA and
the authorized States.
                                          34

-------
      8.2    Municipal Sources

      EPA estimates the total permit fees required of municipal sources to be $94 million per
year  These sources  represent roughly 24.4 percent of all the facilities permitted under the
NPDES program. The total fee is based on 24.4% of the total of the fees collected by EPA and
the authorized States.

       8.3    Federal Sources

       These costs are included in the total fees for private sources. EPA's Permit Compliance
System does not distinguish permits held by federal agencies from non-municipal permits.

       8.4    States

       EPA estimates that States will spend $10 million per year to newly develop or modify
existing fee systems.
                                            35

-------
 9.0    Groundwater Protection

        The Initiative acknowledges the connection between surface water contamination and
 groundwater quality and establishes the protection of groundwater as a specific goal of surface
 water programs.   EPA believes that implementation  of these provisions may help protect
 groundwater from contamination originating from surface water discharges.

        9.1   Private Sources

        EPA estimates that the costs of groundwater protection measures could be between $150
 million and $600 million per year (EPA, 1994a).  Of a  total of approximately 190,000 surface
 impoundments, EPA estimates that 17,000 receive nonhazardous industrial waste (and hence are
 not covered by the hazardous waste disposal provisions  of the Resource Conservation and
 Recovery Act, or RCRA) and are located,in urban areas.  These include 16,232 industrial and
 993 municipal impoundments.  Of these, 70 percent or 12,000 are located in  vulnerable
 groundwater areas and an  estimated 6 percent of these (or  720) are located in areas where
 groundwater is directly connected to surface water (e.g., floodplains).

       The costs to protect groundwater at these sites would range from $740 million (if all
 impoundments require clay liners, (the minimum technology) to $2.9 billion (if all impound-
 ments require clay, plastic  and second clay liners, plus leak  detection systems, the maximum
 technology).  These  impoundments would be addressed over the first 5 years following
 reauthorization, hence the annual costs are between $150 million and $600 million per year.

       9.2    Municipalities

       The impacts of the groundwater provisions on municipalities have not been estimated but
 are expected to be minimal.

       9.3    State Water Programs

       The impacts of the groundwater provisions on states have not been estimated but are
expected to be minimal.

       9.4    Federal Agencies

       The impacts of the groundwater provisions on federal agencies have not been estimated
but are expected to be minimal.
                                         36

-------
      9.5    Benefits14

      The two major categories of benefits from additional groundwater protection measures
are reductions in human health risks and protecting surface water aquatic habitat.

      Reduced Human Health Risk

      In meeting human health objectives, watershed management programs could play a major
role in helping prevent contamination of all sources of drinking water for public water systems.
Preventing contamination of source waters represents  the  first line of defense against public
health risks and escalated monitoring and treatment costs associated with meeting surface and
drinking water quality standards.

       Protection of Surface Water Aquatic Habitat

       Clean groundwater discharging to surface water also has significant ecological benefits,
including:

        >     Protection of economic benefits of in-stream recreation, fisheries and  other
              activities,
        *     Improved water quality and flows,
        >>     In-stream aquatic habitat protection,
        *     Preservation of aquatic biodiversity  and avoided  costs of  future endangered
               species actions.

        In  addition, coordinating CWA and Safe Drinking Water Act requirements results in
 additional benefits from more efficient management of resource by states.
      14 See also the EPA (1994a) background paper "Costs and Benefits Related to Groundwater Provisions in the
  Green Book," January 1994.

                                             37

-------
  10.0   Pollution Prevention Plans
                          *** E?A ^ authorized states *e discretionary authority to require
                          as an NPDES industrial user (TO) permit condition.
         10.1   Private Sources
                           aPProximately 65>^ NPDES permittees would be required to
                           Plans coverin£ toxi' PoUutants. The costs of preparing such plans
  are based on costs reported by the State of Washington,  which requires  similar plans to be

       "   UtS HaZard°US WaSte RedUCti°n Act  °Ver 50° ^ have been deveTopS so
                                      between $10'000  «* $20'000 in  labor per pla
nriont   cf              -                   t0 prepare similar plans under
onented statutes or regulations.  For example, some 20 states have now passed

SSST I?T8 legi,slfon-  To the extent that ^^ or IU facil^ies n
prepared such plans  and the plans are relevant to the requirements under this provson
of these costs would not be incurred by these facilities.
                                                                          prevention-
similar     n              °f P°llution P^vention plans required under the Initiative will be
similar to those in Washington.  Assuming that only 30,000 NPDES permittees would need to

            mmZ* E^f Phases ^ tMf requirement using a 5^ permit renewal Sd?
            ,000 facahties will prepare the plans in each of the first 5 years.  Total annual costs

             '   WlU ^ betW6en $6° miUi°n •Imd  12                     muchless S
 one-
       10.2  Municipalities
       10.3  State Water Programs


       States will incur additional costs for reviewing the facilities' pollution prevention olans
No estimates of the costs for this activity, however, have been developed.             P


       10.4  Federal Agencies
nreWn1           *°. *™*??  * regulation defining  its authority  to  require pollution
prevention plans as a permit condition, and to provide guidance to states on implementing these
requirements. No estimates of the costs for these activities, however, have
                                        38

-------
11.0  Domestic Sewage Exclusion/Pretreatment
      Under the domestic sewage exclusion (DSE) industrial facilities rel «^f ?^J
to sewers are exempt from the requirements of RCRA on the assumption that Clean Water Act
       11.1  Private Sources
       EPA assumes that POTWs would set additional local limits or develop TRAPs that would
 allow facilities facing the loss of the DSE to avoid RCRA impacts.  EPA estimates that toe
 Sti^resSct "nson the DSE would impose additional costs of $282 million per year. Table
 16 summarizes the costs of this provision on private sources.

 costso

 $21,500 per facility per year).
        11.2  Municipalities
        The impacts of the DSE provisions on municipalities have not been estimated but are
  expected  to be minimal.   EPA  has assumed that municipalities  will pass on the cost of
  developing TRAPs to their dischargers.
        11.3   State Water Programs
        The impacts of the DSE provisions on slates have not been estimated but are expected
  to be minimal.
        11.4  Federal Agencies
        The impacts of the DSE provisions on federal agencies have not been estimated but are
  expected to be minimal.  EPA's costs would be for preparing guidance on development and
  implementation of TRAPs.
                                           39

-------
  12.0  Permits/Enforcement/Water Quality Standards

       The enforcement provisions described in the Initiative include a
that
the
 S4 bene^ T"^ 'r  ^^^ ""* ** **** m°re         ach the
 economic benefits of noncompliance, and facilitate the processing of violation cases  The
 sr^s' waiver of sovereign immunity for *&* *»- *^£
       12.1   Private Sources

       Numerous revisions to the enforcement provisions of the CWA will affect private
 sources,  including new enforcement authorities,  changes in fines  and Sdto  aST
 o'n vfoS f ?Tf? enforcement tools- EpA considers  any impacts ffi pro"
 on violating facilities to be a transfer to the federal government, not a true resource cost  The
 potential magnitude of the impacts on violators have not been estimated
       12.2  Municipalities
 are
                                   Uam °n
                                                          not been estimated but
      12.3  State Water Programs
      Impacts of the enforcement provisions on state water programs are estimated at $188
million per year, based on the State Program Costs study (EPA, 1993f).    C*umaiea at *188

      12.4  Federal Agencies


PDA * C?StS,t° f&1^ agendes °f the new enforcement provisions include additional costs to
from $°32 m^T ^Mr ^ aUth°ritieS «* enfor-ment tools. The^ cost Snge
Jrom $32 miUion to $33 million and are summarized in Table 4.15
                                   40

-------
13.0  State Revolving Fund/Construction Grants

      The Initiative will expand the scope of projects eligible for State Revolving Fund(SBF)
assistance, encourage projJ targeting and priority setting, and stimulate the delivery of further
assistance to disadvantaged communities.

       13.1  Private Sources
       The impacts of the new SRF and construction grants provisions on private sources have
not been estimated but are expected to be minimal.

       13.2  Municipalities
       The new SRF and construction grants provisions will have little impact on municipalities.
 Communities that qualify as disadvantaged may benefit from SRF loan  forgiveness.

       13.3   State Water Programs

       State water programs will incur an estimated $8 million annually in additional costs as
 a consequence of the revised SRF and construction grants provisions.  These estimates are based
 upon the State Program Costs study (EPA, 1993f).

        13.4  Federal  Agencies
        The impact of changes in the SRF and. construction grants programs on federal agencies
 (namely, EPA) are estimated to be negligible.
                                            41

-------
 14.0  Monitoring
     ur     .          wil1 encourage EPA to work with states and other federal agencies to
 establish minimum requirements for water quality monitoring and reporting.  States  will be
 required to develop a comprehensive water body inventory under a new Section 305(c).

        14.1   Private Sources

        Changes to the monitoring provisions of the CWA will not have significant additional
 impacts on private sources beyond what is currently being performed.

        14.2   Municipalities

        Changes to the monitoring provisions of the CWA will not have significant additional
 impacts on municipalities beyond what is currently being performed.

        14.3   State Water Programs

        To implement the new monitoring requirements contained in the Initiative states will
 incur an estimated $118  million annually in additional costs.  These estimates are based upon
 the State Program Costs  study (EPA, 1993f).

       14.4   Federal Agencies

       Federal agency impacts of the monitoring provisions will be relatively modest and are
included with the costs of the NFS provisions (Section 3) and watershed provisions  (Section 7)
Among the federal agencies,  the Forest Service has estimated  costs of $37 million per vear to
perform monitoring in federal forests.
                                         42

-------
15.0   Abandoned Mines

       The Initiative recommends that CWA be amended to change and clarify the NPDES
permitting program to target control measures so as  to achieve the greatest improvement in
environmental quality for the limited Federal resources available for inactive and abandoned
mine sites (lAMs) on federal lands without an. identifiable operator.

       15.1  Private Sources

       The Initiative addresses lAMs only on federal lands, and thus there are no impacts on
private sources.

       15.2  Municipalities

       The Initiative addresses lAMs only on federal lands, and thus there are no impacts on
private sources.

       15.3  State Water Programs

       The Initiative addresses lAMs only on federal lands, and thus there are no impacts on
private sources.

       15.4  Federal Agencies

       Under a stringent interpretation of the CWA, remediation efforts would be needed on all
of the estimated 500,000 lAMs.  EPA estimates that, under this interpretation, lAMs that would
need extensive controls range from 15,000 to 50,000.  At an average cost of $220,000 per site,
the total remediation cost incurred over three years would be between $3.3 billion and $11.00
billion, or between $1.1 billion and $3.67 billion per year.  For  the remaining 450,000 to
485,000 lAMs, the annual remediation costs for minimal controls are assumed to be in the range
of $630 per site to $1,885 per site, or between $283 million and $914 million per year.  Thus,
the total cost would range between $1.38 billion and $4.48 billion per year, as shown in Table
22.

       Under  the Initiative, EPA could issue  general permits to all federal  land  managers
responsible for these sites in each state (rather than individual permits to each IAM).  These
general permits would require remediation at 15,000 to 50,000 sites  that  are estimated to cause
water quality impairments.  However, these expenditures would be incurred over a ten year
period.  Therefore, the total cost would range between $3.3 billion and  $11.00 billion, or
between $330 million and $1.10 billion per year, as shown in Table 20.  The remaining lAMs,
between 450,000 and 485,000 sites, would not require any controls because they are assumed
to not cause any water quality impairment.

       The impacts of the Initiative,  compared with the potential  mitigation required under


                                          43

-------
current programs, will be to reduce potential costs.  Total annual cost savings (or costs avoided)
would be between $1.05 billion and $3.48 billion per year (Table 21).

       15.5   Benefits16

       The major categories of benefits associated with IAM mitigation include:

       +      Improved ecological and human health benefits,

       *•      Increased property values,

       >      Increased commercial and recreational fishery production,

       >      Avoided costs of treating drinking water supplies, and

       >      Decreased  water treatment  costs for  existing  mining operations and  other
              industrial activities.

       Mitigating lAMs  not only results in  restoration of aquatic resources but  also can
significantly contribute to the enhancement of water-related activities.  In so doing, mitigation
will strengthen  an important part of the West's economic base and contribute to ongoing
economic development.

       Specific examples of benefits from mitigating lAMs are discussed below.

       Fish,  Wildlife, and Recreation

       *      The economic value of recreational fishing on DOI lands has been estimated to
              be $4.0 billion per  year.   EPA estimates that  the  fishing-related benefits
              associated with reducing all IAM impairments total $42 million per year.

       >      The State of Colorado estimates that the annual revenue associated with fishing
              in Golden would increase by $750,000 per year if releases from lAMs discharg-
              ing to Clear Creek were mitigated.

       Drinking Water

       *      Westminster, Colorado, estimates that it costs about $15,000 to $20,000 per year
              to provide additional  treatment  of its  water supply to remove metals  from
              upstream IAM sites.
    16 See also the EPA (1994b) background paper "CWA Benefits of Mitigation of Inactive and Abandoned Mines
on Federal Lands," January 1994.

                                           44

-------
>      High concentrations of zinc from lAMs have forced Golden to provide special
       waste disposal for sludge from its drinking water system serving 14,000 people.
       The city estimates that it spends an additional $15,000 per year for sludge testing,
       transporting, and landfilling.

Agriculture

*•      lAMs can have adverse impacts on irrigation water supplies.  EPA has warned
       that the Summitville mine in Colorado may have possible toxic discharges into the
       Alamosa River, which irrigates many farms and ranches in the area.

Human Safety and Health

*•      Based on data in the Western  Governors Association report, lAMs on  federal
       lands are responsible for accidents resulting in an average of 20 fatalities and 40
       serious injuries each year.

*•      The National Park Service has identified 9,934 hazards associated with the 2,000
       lAMs in the parks, including unmarked mine openings, abandoned explosives,
       unidentified chemicals and other wastes, and contaminated streams and lakes used
       by park visitors and wildlife.

>      Safety risks are expected to increa.se as rural areas of western states become more
       populated, and recreation expands on the BLM  and FS lands.

+      Some 179 children living within a mile of the Bunker Hill silver mine were at
       risk of suffering cognitive skill impairments as  consequence of levels of lead in
       their blood.

Economic

*      A 1993 study of the impacts of the reform of the Mining Act of 1872 estimates
       that IAM reclamation activities could generate between 2,000 and 10,000 jobs in
       communities  suffering from the effects of the  mining industry's  shrinking
       unemployment base.  Many of these jobs will rely on workers with experience in
       the mining and mineral services who have lost employment with a sluggish
       mining industry.
                                    45

-------
 16.0  Market Incentives - Effluent Trading

       The Initiative  provides  opportunities  for  innovative  approaches  to water  quality
 improvement. The goal is to stimulate cost savings for dischargers, better institutional efficiency
 in program design and implementation, and support for continuous efforts to loadings reductions
 and environmental gains.  In addition, the Initiative will provide incentive for developing new
 technologies and creating new  markets.

       The Initiative promotes trading in four types of effluent reduction:

       *      Point Source - Nonpoint Source Trading
       >      Point Source - Point Source Trading
       *      Nonpoint Source - Nonpoint Source Trading
       >      Pretreatment Trading

       The sections below describe the potential for cost savings to private sources from each
 type of trading,  based  upon an EPA Office of Water analysis of Clean Water Act economic
 incentives (EPA, 1993a).

       16.1   Point Source - Nonpoint  Source Trading

       Cost savings from two case studies indicate that the range in savings could be between
 $1 million and $12 million per  site.  EPA's Water Body System has identified about 940 water
 bodies that can benefit from nutrient trading. The number could be smaller after future NFS and
 pending point  source controls are implemented in  impaired water bodies. Assuming the actual
 number of appropriate sites is half the 940 (i.e., 470), the potential savings overall could range
 from $611  million to $5.6 billion.

       16.2   Point Source - Point Source

       Actual  savings from point-point trading will vary from site to site because of differences
 between sites: size, water quality needs, availability of  technology, number of  participants,
program design costs, etc.  EPA's Water Body System has identified about 210 water bodies that
 can benefit from  trading. Data  from 12 simulation studies show that the potential savings range
 from $40,000 to  $9.2 million per site. Potential cost savings could thus be in the range of $8.4
 million to $1.9 billion.

       16.3  Nonpoint Source - Nonpoint Source

       The potential for nonpoint-nonpoint trading exists, but sufficient information is not
available at this time to develop estimates.
                                         46

-------
       16.4  Pretreatment Trading

       Potential savings due to pretreatment trading are based on a case study of one large
POTW (Field's Point in Providence, RI) that has a large number of industrial dischargers,
including  117 metal finishing facilities. Simulation shows that the loading of nickel can be
reduced by 20 percent, at a cost savings of $580,000 (81 percent) from the costs of across-the-
board reduction of 20 percent for all metal finishers. Sixteen industrial dischargers can install
advanced treatment systems,  and the POTW could provide removal credits to 97 dischargers,
thus eliminating the need to install additional treatment at these facilities.

       The simulation study  identified 62 PQTWs as potential candidates for trading.  These
POTWs support a large number of industrial dischargers, including a fair number that discharge
a single pollutant.  Extrapolation from the  Field's Point data suggests that the potential cost
savings is $39 million.  Actual savings will depend on the POTW, the type of pollutant(s)
traded, the number of dischargers participating, program design costs, etc.  Potential savings
could be larger if additional POTWs could participate.

       These potential decreases in costs should not be viewed as future costs avoided (or not
incurred) because dischargers will not be installing additional controls; to meet new requirements.
These potential cost savings  should not be viewed as decreasing other costs discussed in this
report but instead would represent reductions in the cost of additional controls needed for growth
or to meet water quality standards.

       Total potential savings from all types of trading  range from $658 million to $7.5 billion
per year.
                                           47

-------
 17.0   Monetized Benefits: Urban Areas17

        This section presents an estimate of the overall benefits that are likely to result from
 adoption of the Initiative's provisions that address urban sources of water pollution, including
 CSO, storm water, and toxics.

        17.1   Introduction

        The nation's lakes, rivers, bays, and oceans are enjoyed for their aesthetic qualities and
 for their recreation opportunities  (e.g., fishing,  waterfowl hunting, swimming,  boating, and
 viewing). They also support a commercial fishing industry, and surface waters are diverted for
 food processing, other industrial uses (e.g., cooling), forestry, animal husbandry, and agriculture
 (i.e., irrigation).   In addition to  supplying these and other current services for humans, the
 preservation of some aquatic ecosystems may provide nonuse or passive values.  For example,
 these values may stem from the  desires of the current generation to preserve certain ecosystems
 for the uses that future generations may have for them. Furthermore, some individuals believe
 that society has a stewardship responsibility  even if the human uses for those particular
 ecosystems are unknown.

        Surface waters have yet another use: as a waste receptacle for discharges from industry
 and run-off from both rural and  urban areas.  In spite of the great assimilative capacity of these
 waters, they can be degraded by excessive pollutant loadings to the  detriment of  the other
 beneficial uses to society.  This section presents an estimate of the range of economic benefits
 that may result from adoption of the Initiative's provisions dealing with urban sources in the
 CWA.   Due to  uncertainties along each step of the process  from  implementation of the
 provisions to the resultant changes in water quality and finally to the effects on human welfare,
 the estimate of the  economic benefit range may understate or overstate  actual benefits.

       17.1   Limitations

       The analysis of the economic benefits focusing on urban areas draws upon information
 provided by a number of disparate data sources, and relies upon a number of assumptions.  The
 synthesis of information introduces considerable uncertainty into the final numeric values. Major
 sources of uncertainty that limit our ability to be confident in the numeric results include: (1)
 the actual extent of  impaired waters; (2) the method of attributing responsibility for impairment;
 (3) our assumptions about  the efficacy of the provisions; and (4) the reliance upon secondary
 sources of information when estimating the economic values of environmental quality.  The
 absence of reliable information on all of these elements plays a critical role in our ability to draw
 conclusions about the benefits that will result from the Initiative.
    trj
      See also the EPA (1994h) background paper "Aggregate Economic Benefits for Controlling Selected Urban-
Based Pollution Sources," February 1994.


                                           48

-------
       One of the more significant points of uncertainty in the analysis relates to the monetary
valuation of economic benefits for the dominant benefit category--the enhanced freshwater
recreation,  aesthetics,  and  non-use benefits  that ensue with the proposed  water  quality
improvements.   The absence of alternative data sources constrained  us  to make use  of a
published, yet dated, contingent valuation research study that measured a household's use and
non-use values for national and, by apportionment techniques,  more localized improvements in
freshwater rivers and lakes.  Criticism has been levied against the validity of empirical results
for non-use values derived using prior contingent valuation research methods.  Several issues
raised in the ongoing debate about this valuation method bear directly upon the interpretation of
the numeric results provided by our source materials.

       Independent of this  debate, further uncertainties are introduced by transferring the
research results to the policies and environmental concerns addressed, by the Initiative. The wide
range of values demonstrates an attempt to capture the impact of these uncertainties on the
numeric estimate.  All told,  it is difficult to conclude whether the presented numeric ranges
underestimate or overestimate the actual benefits. We suggest that the numerical results best
serve to indicate the overall order-of-magnitude of the benefits. Based upon our experience in
undertaking the analysis, we can further conclude that considerable gaps persist in our ability
to  measure and evaluate the relationships between  water quality  conditions  and economic
activities, even twenty years after the passage of the principal legislation designed to identify and
address water pollution problems. The Administration's Initiative contains provisions to help
rectify this situation in the future.

       17.3  Methodology and Assumptions

       This analysis  begins with  informed  judgement about the extent of  water quality
improvement that may result from implementation of CSO and storm sewer provisions relative
to current conditions.  We assume that in all cases where CSOs or storm sewers are thought to
be the  leading source of impaired urban waters (i.e.,  based upon the 305(b) Reports), the
implementation of these provisions will restore these waters  to fishable and  swimmable quality.
Furthermore,  for those waters where other sources must share significant responsibility with
CSOs and  storm sewers for precluding  the attainment of fishable and swimmable quality,  we
assume two things.  First, we attribute 50% of the responsibility to CSOs and storm sewers.
Second, we assume that the implementation of other provisions of the act in combination with
the CSO and  storm sewer provisions will result in the attainment of fishable and swimmable
quality in the affected waters.  Thus, although we recognize  that uncertainty about the actual
extent of impaired waters may lead to an over  or underestimate of the economic benefit range,
our method of attributing responsibility for impairments and our assumptions about the efficacy
of the provisions may tend to overestimate the economic benefit range.

        Beyond the physical, chemical, and biological changes that may result from the CSO and
 storm sewer provisions, for the economic evaluation it is also necessary to estimate the effects
 these changes have on humans and other economic entities (i.e., industry).  For the purposes of
 this assessment we aggregate these sources of benefits into four primary categories: 1. enhanced
                                           49

-------
 freshwater recreation, aesthetics, and nonuse benefits; 2. enhanced marine recreation, aesthetic,
 and nonuse benefits; 3. cost savings or increased output for withdrawal or diversionary users;
 and, 4. cost savings or increased output for commercial fisheries. In the event that human health
 effects were not subsumed in the benefit estimates of one or more of the four primary categories
 we include it as a fifth category. In addition to quantifying an economic benefit range for each
 of these categories, we mention  the other potential changes in the economic activities of
 consumers and producers that could not be quantified.

       The existing economic literature on the benefits of water quality improvements suggests
 that enhanced water-based recreation and aesthetics and the non-use values that people may hold
 for the preservation of the nation's aquatic ecosystems is the largest source of quantifiable
 economic benefits.  The sheer  numbers of people who recreate  in a water setting each year
 testifies to the importance of this resource.  More to the point, a growing number of economic
 studies are documenting the influence that water quality characteristics have on which  water
 bodies people choose to visit, how often they engage in water-based recreation activities,  and
 how much they are willing to pay for incremental improvements in water quality.  Less abundant
 are  the studies that demonstrate  the linkage between water  quality  improvements and the
 resultant increases in individuals' non-use values, but there is general agreement that these values
 exist.  This is based in part upon survey responses from people who do not currently use the
 nation's surface waters for recreation or for their aesthetics but nonetheless indicate a willingness
 to pay for achieving certain water  quality standards.

       There are no primary studies that attempt to estimate the enhanced recreation, aesthetics,
 and non-use benefits of water quality improvements that may be attributed to the CSO and storm
 sewer provisions of the Initiative.   However, there is a study that attempts to ascertain the total
 economic value that households place on  the achievement of incremental improvements in
 virtually all of the nation's lakes, rivers, and streams (i.e., marine waters were not included)
 (Mitchell and Carson, 1984, 1986; Carson and Mitchell, 1993; and Lyon and Farrow, 1992).
 As a part of this research effort, a method of allocating the household's willingness to pay for
 improvements in local water quality was also devised.  This method of apportioning  total
 willingness to pay for subnational changes in water quality was "validated" by comparing the
 resultant estimates with those of studies that valued similar incremental improvements (i.e., from
 beatable to fishable and from fishable to swimmable) at the local level (Mitchell and Carson,
 1986; Carson and Mitchell,  1993).   Therefore,  we use Mitchell and Carson's research to
 suggest the range in enhanced recreation, aesthetics and non-use benefits from improvements in
 urban freshwaters that may result from the Initiative. Key assumptions in this analysis involve:
 the number of households proximate to the improved waters versus  all other households, the
proportion of improved waters  in the household's State relative to all of the State's degraded
waters,  the  abundance of clean alternatives proximate to the household, the  abundance of
substitute clean waters in the state, and the accuracy of the original study.  Uncertainty about
each of these factors leads to a wide range for the economic benefit estimate. Moreover, to say
whether the range itself underestimates or overestimates  the  actual benefits is impossible,
especially when uncertainties about the actual physical water quality changes are factored into
the analysis.
                                          50

-------
       The  remaining quantifiable economic  benefits (i.e., enhanced marine recreation,
aesthetics, and non-use values; commercial fishing; water diversions; and human health) are
small by comparison with the freshwater benefits. In addition, the economic basis for estimating
these benefits is less defensible. We rely entirely upon secondary studies to suggest a plausible
range of benefits for these categories.  Finally, we mention briefly other possible economic
benefits to people and economic entities that may or  may not be subsumed in the foregoing
analyses.  We believe that mentioning these potential economic effects is important because we
cannot rule them out on the basis of current knowledge. A more detailed discussion of how the
benefits are quantified and monetized  is included in Appendix D.

       17.4  Summary of Benefits Results

       Monetized Benefits: Urban Areas.  EPA estimates further that the aggregate benefits
of pollution control in urban areas will eventually produce quantifiable benefits of between $0.8
billion and $6.0 billion per year (Table 18).  The range recognizes the uncertainty associated
with these estimates.  For example, the upper end of the range may be  an underestimate in the
extreme case where the new provisions are 100 percent effective, households care very much
about the resultant improvements relative to the other waters in their sitate, and the unqualified
benefits turn out to be significant relative to the quantified benefits.  Similarly, the lower end
of the range may be an overestimate in the extreme event that the new provisions fail to improve
water  quality to fishable and swimmable levels, or the changes in water quality have no effect
on the economic activities of consumers and producers.

        Quantified Benefit Categories.  The first beneficial category relates to the total value
that households place on the enhanced recreation, aesthetics, and non-use values associated with
improved urban freshwaters.  The most comprehensive assessment of such benefits is actually
too inclusive. A contingent valuation  study conducted by Mitchell and Carson (1984, 1986), and
updated by Carson and Mitchell (1991, 1993) values  freshwater quality improvements  beyond
 the expanse of waters whose quality will be improved as a consequence of the urban provisions
 of the Initiative.  However, Mitchell and Carson (1986) show how their research results can be
 used to value localized improvements such as may occur once the CSO, storm water,  and other
 urban-based provisions are implemented. According to Mitchell and Carson (1986), respondents
 to their survey were willing to allocate 67%  of  their national willingness to pay to  achieve
 improvements at the state level.   Then, Mitchell and Carson (1986) devised guidelines for
 further reducing this percentage for sub-state water quality improvements.

        To implement their strategy, we divided the population into two types of people; those
 living in urban areas proximate to the water quality  change, and all  other households.  The
 allocation of households into these two groups was based upon an  estimate of the number of
 households living in urban areas proximate  to  waters that have  not attained fishable and
 swimmable conditions.   The  simulations from a  water  quality  model  that linked urban
 populations to waters in EPA's Reach File 1 (Bondelid and Cooter, 1994) provided an estimate
 of the urban populations that are proximate to impaired waters.  By "proximate" is meant living
 in a city or town that has the same reach designation as the river segment.  The 305(b) reports


                                            51

-------
 provided the estimate of the percentage of impaired urban waters that are due, at least in part,
 to CSOs, storm water, and other urban-based pollution.  Both  estimates were based  upon
 nonrandom  samples  of their respective populations,  and yet we used these estimates to
 extrapolate to the full national populations of households and freshwaters. Unfortunately, we
 do not know whether the effect of this extrapolation is to under- or over- estimate the number
 of households that are most proximate to improved waters.

        The households living proximate to improved urban waters are likely to benefit most
 from the successful implementation of the urban provisions in the Initiative.  We assign them
 a range of benefits using Mitchell and Carson's lower bound of 12% and upper bound of 67%
 of their total willingness to pay.  The high end of the range is only appropriate if the improved
 waters represent virtually all of the previously degraded waters in the household's state and/or
 the households care most about their state waters they adjoin. Households not located along
 these improved waters are assigned a lower bound of 0% and an upper bound of 12%, as the
 improved waters are located further away and substitution possibilities are relatively abundant.
 For both types of households, the estimates are further reduced by 50% in cases where other
 sources of pollutants besides CSOs and storm water are assumed to be limiting factors that may
 preclude fishable and  swimmable water quality conditions.

        The number of urban households expected to directly benefit from improvements in their
 local waters are considerable.  We estimate that 29 million urban households border waters
 currently incapable of supporting suitable fishing conditions, and 41 million households adjoin
 water that fail to meet criteria used to classify swimmable designated use conditions.  Of these
 households, nearly 4 out of every 10 are expected to experience a full recovery of their waters
 to support these designated uses  as a consequence of implementing the urban-based Initiative
 provisions.  The remainder may see partial or no improvement because additional measures will
 be required to bring the affected waters to fishable and swimmable conditions, measures that are
 presently mandated under existing environmental statutes but have yet to be fully implemented.

       The annual economic benefits to the first group of households expecting full recovery of
 their waters ranges from $0.4 to $2.0 billion. For households in those urban areas where these
 provisions will serve to eliminate some of the problems, when the remaining limiting factors are
 overcome, their benefits are expected to range between $0.3 to $1.6 billion.  Lastly, the range
 of benefits to persons outside of these affected areas but expected to  enjoy use or  non-use
 benefits as a result of improvements in these areas is zero to $1.1 billion.  Adding these three
 categories of households, the consequences of bringing these urban area waters into designated
 fishable and swimmable water quality conditions yields a national total annual benefit estimate
 between $650 million and $4.7 billion.  As can be seen, the majority of the monetary benefits
 are associated  with those urban households that are located in  areas  having  water quality
problems.

       The wide range in estimated benefits reflects, in part, the uncertainties in the analysis
regarding the strength of these households' preferences for achieving improvements in their local
impaired waters. Their values should be dependent upon the availability of possible substitutes,
                                          52

-------
which is a function of the scope and magnitude of the severity of water quality problems present
in the state from both urban and other pollution sources.  The statistics provided by the draft
1992 305(b) report (EPA, 1993b), identify urban runoff and storm water as a leading source of
impairment in 24,100 assessed river miles (30% of non-agricultural impaired and assessed miles,
or 10% of all impaired and assessed miles, or 3% of all assessed miles,  or 0.7% of all river
miles in the nation).  Similarly, for lakes, reservoirs, and ponds, urban runoff and storm water
are leading sources of impairment in 1.31 million acres (52% of non-agricultural impaired and
assessed acres, or 24.1% of impaired and assessed acres, or 7.1%  of all assessed acreage, or
4.8% of all lake acreage in the nation).  These types of statistics could be used to attempt to
locate where along the range of values expressed in the Mitchell and Carson  research, these
specific urban provisions would be expected to fulfill. The 305(b) data provided on mileage and
acreage of freshwater that was assessed and found to be impaired  by urban-based sources of
pollution does not, absent further assumptions or additional information,  permit us to select a
narrower range of values to assign to households. Still,  we believe that the 305(b) data suggests
that the calculated upper end  of the range constitutes a very optimistic (i.e., high) estimate of
the quantified benefits in this  category.

        The marine recreational fishing category captures the anticipated  economic benefits to
persons who now participate or would likely participate in marine sportfishing and shellfishing
activities in the event water quality improvements would result from controls placed on urban
sources identified in the Initiative. The range of estimated  economic benefits is due to the
uncertain relationship between water quality changes, reductions in urban pollution sources, and
the expected economic value  of achieving water quality improvements.  Unlike the freshwater
recreation benefits, these estimates do not include possible non-use values households may hold
for improvements in these areas.  At present, an estimated 92 million marine recreational trips
are taken every year.  As  a  result of water quality improvements due to the Initiative,  these
numbers are expected to increase by 10 percent to 20 percent above current rates.  Using these
increases, in combination with estimates on the economic benefits associated with each trip, we
 estimate that the anticipated annual economic benefits  to marine recreational fishing from the
 urban-based provisions will be between $40 million and $440  million.  The literature does not
 support including other consumptive recreation activities despite evidence of the influence  of
 water quality parameters on  swimming and boating in coastal waters.   National estimates  of
 marine recreation participation rates are not available currently for these activities, and it is not
 known how water pollution  controls have improved water quality and  influenced recreation
 behavior.  Finally,  the literature on nonuse values associated with nondegraded or improved
 marine water quality is almost nonexistent, with the exception of lost nonuse values due to oil
 spills.

        The marine nonconsumptive recreation benefit category consists of recreational activity
 other than fishing and swimming that occurs  within estuaries  or along the coast.   Current
 participation rates and estimates of the economic benefits associated with viewing of wildlife are
 used as a foundation for the benefits of attaining further water quality improvements. The range
 in  benefits is the result of the  same uncertainties described  in the marine recreation fishing
 discussion  above.  Also, non-use values to households for water quality improvements affecting


                                            53

-------
 these activities are not included in the estimates. Recent surveys of recreational activity indicate
 that nearly 7  million persons engage in  oceanside viewing of wildlife, and an estimated 5.6
 million persons visit wetlands and marshes to observe wildlife.  Water quality improvements due
 to the Initiative's provisions are expected to increase participation in these activities by 10
 percent to 20 percent above current rates.  The estimated number of trips per person and
 economic benefits per  trip are used to calculate  the potential benefits  to nonconsumptive
 recreation activity from water quality improvements associated with the urban-based provisions.
 The range of annual benefits is estimated at between $30 million and $300 million.

        The estimated benefits to marine and freshwater commercial fisheries from anticipated
 improvements in water quality conditions  are based upon information about current commercial
 activity.  The potential gains from reducing urban source loadings of pollution are assumed to
 be a function of current  benefits associated with existing water quality  conditions and the
 estimated  contribution these urban  sources  make to overall  water  quality limitations.  The
 estimated values capture benefits to  both commercial producers and households resulting from
 expected increases in stocks offish and shellfish and other efficiency gains to commercial fishing
 operations.  The current ex-vessel value of coastal fisheries is approximately'$1.8 billion per
 year.  Water  quality improvements due to the Initiative are expected to increase  baseline
 economic values associated with these activities by 10 to 20 percent above current rates.  Given
 the expected contribution of changes in urban-based  pollution loadings to these improvements,
 the total range of economic  benefits to commercial fisheries is estimated between $40 million
 and $190 million.  These figures include benefits to the commercial industry and consumers of
 seafood from an expected increase  in the quantity  and  quality of harvested seafood.18 We
 should note that a recent review of studies that demonstrate linkages between fish populations
 and water quality was conducted by Strand (1993). He found only two studies that demonstrated
 credible relationships between pollution and fish populations for some species in a few coastal
 locations.  The paucity of analysis may be due to a lack of trend data on pollution and fish
 populations or, alternatively, because the effects are  not generally present.  The study submits
 that the infrastructure for assessing  the incremental benefits of implementing existing or new
 policies is  not present, and recommends collecting the data and doing the analysis  in order to
 guide spending on water pollution control to the areas where it will have an effect.  Such an
 investment in research may  be necessary to protect the  billion-dollar fishing industry,  while
 avoiding wasting resources on programs that do not work.

       Improvements  in  urban water quality are expected  to  result in reduced  costs  to
 commercial, industrial, and municipal consumers who use these waters as an  input to production
 of goods and services, including drinking water. For example, improved surface water that is
 diverted to the public water  supply results in cost savings for treating drinking  water. In the
 manufacturing sector, the cooling and processing costs in the food and beverages, textiles, paper,
 chemicals,  and steel  industries are somewhat reduced by higher quality intake water.   For
      The health benefits of uncontaminated seafood is included in the health benefit estimates. Consumers benefit
in this category as a result of the lower prices or the greater supply of seafood.
                                          54

-------
thermoelectric energy production, treated water is used for reactor and condenser cooling to
reduce corrosion, particularly in cases where cooling water is recalculated.  The treatment costs
may be reduced by higher quality intake water. The influence of urban source controls on
withdrawal or diversionary uses is not expected to be substantial, due to the presence of other
limiting factors associated with these waters (e.g., naturally occurring elements)  but some
marginal cost savings may occur.  In this analysis,  only manufacturing and drinking  water
suppliers are included in the  quantitative estimates.  Estimates of the current costs of water
treatment, or damages caused  by  poor water quality, serve as the baseline measure of potential
benefits  Current conditions are expected to improve after having reduced urban-based pollution
discharges identified in  the Initiative.  The overall level of improvements reflected in costs
savings to some industries and manufacturing facilities is expected to be fairly low, probably no
more than 1 to 5 percent of current costs. As a result, the  expected annual economic benefits
to diversionary uses of water  will fall between $20 million  and $80 million.

       The ability to provide  greater opportunities to swim  and fish in the nation's waters also
provides  for  the reduction from acute and  chronic risks  posed by chemicals and bacteria
discharged from urban-based pollution sources.  The human  health benefits of reduced exposure
to  these types of compounds are calculated, using  information on changes in the expected
 number of persons exposed to a subset of pollutants  originating  with urban dischargers.  As a
 consequence  of controls, the number of beach closures and advisories  will be  expected to
 decline • and  participation will  rise.   Current participation  rates in freshwater  and  marine
 swimming are estimated at 450 million person-days per year.  Of these, between two and four
 million acute illnesses  are expected  to result from  current exposures  to pathogens.   Given
 information on the duration  and costs associated  with these types of illnesses,  the expected
 reductions  in risks from the urban-based Initiative provisions will result in annual economic
 benefits of $30 million  to $100 million.  Risks from the  consumption of contaminated  seafood
 are also expected to diminish as a consequence of reducing urban-based pollution sources. In
 particular,  risks  to those persons that partake in greater  than  average  consumption rates ot
 seafood (e g., subsistence fishingpersons) will be reduced.  The expected reduction in cases of
 chronic illnesses attributed to consumption of contaminated seafood, and the value of reducing
 these types of risks, results  in  an  estimated range of benefits between $40 million and $220
 million.  Adding these two separate estimates together yields a total health benefit range of $40
 million to  $320 million.

        Unqualified Benefit Categories.  There are a number of benefit categories  that are
  known to  be affected by water quality conditions,  and  hence are likely  to be affected by the
  adoption of the urban-based provisions in the Initiative.  However, the absence of information
  limits the capability to produce monetary estimates for these categories.  Rather than completely
  omit them from the discussion, we have elected to briefly  discuss some of the more significant
  categories so as to enable the policies to be evaluated  with as much information as  feasible,
  whether it be quantitative or qualitative in nature.

         The impacts of the provisions on marine recreation swimming are not fully captured in
  the above section on quantitative impacts.  Some of the human health benefits are considered,


                                              55

-------
  but the non-health benefits from the provision of more and higher quality marine recreation
  opportunities have not been included.  In addition to the selected acute and chronic effects of a
  few of the many pollutants that will be addressed by the Initiative provisions, there are many
  other hpman health effects that have not been quantified.  Potential effects on reproductive
  systems and  several other acute and  chronic effects from pollutants discharged from urban
  sources were excluded from the quantitative measures. Recreational hunting activities are likely
  to benefit from the provision of a greater number and higher quality habitat necessary to support
  different forms of wildlife. The availability of living space, supply of food sources and impacts
  on reproduction have been associated with environmental pollutants.  Reductions of pollutants
  that limit the ability of natural systems to support wildlife will result in economic benefits to
  hunters and other persons interested in nonconsumptive recreation activity occurring on or near
  freshwater. Although most of the nation's waters are thought to support boating activity  it is
  plausible that further improvements in both freshwater and marine water quality conditions will
  enhance the enjoyment of recreational  boating, and  thus may have positive  economic value to
  persons  engaged in these activities.   These are thought the  constitute some  of the more
  significant benefit categories, as measured by current participation rates or level of economic
  activity.

        In addition to measuring the benefits to parties that make  direct use  of resources
  supported by cleaner marine and freshwater, there is another economic value  individuals may
 hold for environmental protection that does not rely on the  use  of the amenity in question
 Individuals can express a willingness to  pay for the protection of environmental conditions
 absent any personal desire to participate in the above activities supported by these conditions'
 In the freshwater fishing and swimming benefit estimates, we were able to include the non-user
 Benefits in  the range of estimates because of the type of source  material used  in the valuation
 step for this part of the analysis.  For  the remaining benefit  categories,  the nonuse value
 component, if positive, has been omitted. Studies on nonuse values have documented substantial
 economic values for some types of environmental goods.  The lack of reliable information on
 these other categories prevents the inclusion of these values in the quantitative estimates.

        The ability to support better functioning natural systems may provide a way to substitute
 for currently operated and maintained manmade systems. For example, natural systems can help
 provide flood control services,  water storage, and purification processes, and reduce the need
 for dredging of disposed sediment. The potential avoided costs from improvements in water
 quality can be significant.  Estimates for some of these avoided costs have been captured in parts
 of the cost analysis for the Initiative's provisions (e.g., agricultural practices).

       A final category of unqualified benefits not  listed in the table concerns the potential
 enhancements in overall economic productivity and effirimny that  may  be gained  as a
 consequence of improving the  quality of the nation's waters.  In some cases, underutilized
 economic resources devoted to the protection of the environment can lead to greater levels of
 overall production and social welfare than if these resources were to remain underemployed
Most often, these types of benefits are treated as secondary benefits, and are not expected to
contribute to net improvements to overall economic activity measures.  In general this is
                                          56

-------
probably true, but it is possible that for some specific local areas, shifting of economic resources
into the protection of the environment may yield positive net economic benefits.  However, were
we to include this information in the analysis, we would need to introduce other indirect costs
not fully captured in the description of economic costs estimated to result from these provisions.
Failure to develop a fully balanced description of costs and benefits could distort comparisons
between  the two categories.  As the cost analysis was  not developed along these lines, a
reference to potential indirect benefits is omitted in Table 18.

       Costs- Urban Areas.  Provisions in the Initiative that address urban areas are loosely
defined to include storm water Phase I and Phase II, CSOs and toxics controls.  The annualized
costs of these provisions  for all sectors is  estimated to be between $9.9 and $13.9 billion, as
shown in Table 17.

       Net Benefits:  Urban Areas. The monetized benefits of the Initiative ($0.8 billion to
$6.0 billion), assuming benefits are realized immediately, contrast with between $9.9 billion to
$13.9 billion in incremental annualized costs for urban areas.

       However, benefits are unlikely to be realized immediately. To illustrate how the gradual
 attainment of the benefits may influence the benefit-cost  comparison, the figures in Tables 17
 and 18 show the annualized monetary costs  and benefits from control of urban sources under
 proposed and  pending spending.  In Table  18, two of the three aggregate benefit  estimates
 provide for the gradual attainment of benefits, applying different discount rates to an assumed
 future stream  of benefits.   The  selection of the two discount rates reflects Administration
 guidelines on the application of discounting to costs and benefits (seven  percent), as compared
 with  the use of a  social rate of time preference  (three percent).  The  discounted annualized
 benefits are some twenty to thirty percent lower than the annualized benefit estimate that fails
 to account for the expected delays  in achieving  tangible water quality improvements.  This
 serves to demonstrate the sensitivity of the results to both the time and  discounting features of
 the analysis.

        Comparing the annualized costs and benefits under any of the three annualized benefit
 estimation scenarios, it is apparent that the  range of estimated  monetary costs and benefits do
 not presently overlap. Despite information of this type, the Administration feels it is important
 to proceed with the Initiative for several reasons.   As stated throughout the text, and documented
 in the supplemental materials, there are great uncertainties associated  with both the cost and
 benefit estimates that are not captured in the presentation of the numerical results. For example,
 although the national cost estimates have attempted to  account for targeting of watersheds in
 need of improvement and emphasized prevention measures over comrnand-and-control strategies,
 there are  uncertainties  in the analysis because  of the  difficulty of fully accounting for the
 consequences of providing flexibility in the  identification of problems and solutions.  There are
  also  a number of tangible benefits for which monetary estimates have not been developed.   So
  as to better inform decisionmakers and the public in the  future EPA is proposing a comprehen-
  sive benefit-cost study of  the pollution controls  in the CWA reauthorization.  This  study will
  reduce the uncertainties surrounding the benefits and cost estimates.
                                             57

-------
       Despite the uncertainties, an important contribution of the economic analysis has been
its ability to document the significant savings the Initiative is proposing compared with  the
requirements called for in the existing legislation.  In addition, considerable effort was given to
developing cost-effective policies where new efforts are needed to achieve the goals of the Clean
Water Act.  Therefore,  the Initiative demonstrates a genuine effort to achieve cost-effective
regulatory management approaches to  improving  the nation's  polluted waters    Equally
important, the public's right to enjoy clean waters, and the demonstration of their preferences
through  environmentally protective federal legislation,  have  served as  inputs  into  the
development of Administration policy.  Strong public  support for additional pollution control
programs persists, and the Initiative will address what the Administration believes are the most
significant remaining problems.
                                         58

-------
                                  REFERENCES

Bondelid, T. and W.S. Cooler.  1994. "A Tool for Evaluating the Effectiveness of the Clean
Water Act." Research Triangle  Institute Project No.  35U-5726-3, Center for Environmental
Analysis, Research Triangle Institute, P.O. Box 12194, Research Triangle Park, NC 27709.

Carson, R.T. and R.C. Mitchell. 1991. "The Value of Clean Water: The Public's Willingness
to Pay  for Boatable, Fishable,  and Swimmable Quality Water." Economics Department,
University of California, San Diego.

Carson, R.T. and R.C. Mitchell. 1993. "The Value of Clean Water: The Public's Willingness
to Pay for Boatable, Fishable, and Swimmable Quality Water." Water Resources Research 29(7):
2445-2454.

DOD.  1993a.    "Clean  Water  Act Reauthorization 'Initiative' Resource Requirements."
Memorandum from Michael L. Davis, U.S. Department of Defense, Department of the Army,
Office of the  Assistant Secretary  of Army  (Civil Works), to the  EPA Office  of Water.
November 19,  1993.

DOD.  1993b.  "Federal Agency Costing of the Administration Initiative." Memorandum from
Josephine S. Huang, U.S. Department of Defense, Office of the Undersecretary of Defense, to
EPA Office of Water.  November 17, 1993.

DOE.  1993. "S. 1114 Federal Agency Cost Estimates."  Memorandum from David Moses to
Mark Luttner,  EPA Office of Water. September 13,  1993.

DOI. 1994.  "Incremental Impacts of S. 1114 and the  EPA Initiative for the Department of the
Interior."  Memorandum from Gregory E. Schwartz, U.  S. Department of the Interior,
Geological Survey, to Mahesh Podar, EPA Office of  Water.  January 27, 1994.

EPA 1990a.  "National Water Quality Inventory: 1988 Report  to Congress."  EPA Office of
Water.  1990.

EPA. 1990b. "Environmental Investments: The Cost of a Clean Environment." EPA-230-11-90-
283.  EPA Office of Policy, Planning and Evaluation. November 1990.

EPA.  1992.   "National Water Quality Inventory: 1990 Report to Congress."  EPA 503/9-
92/006. EPA Office of Water.  April 1992.

EPA.  1993. "Draft Combined Sewer Overflow Control Policy." EPA Office of Water.

 EPA.  1993a.   "Economic Incentives in the Clean Water Act: Some Preliminary Results."
 Presented by  Mahesh Podar and Mark Luttner, EPA Office of Water, at the 86th Annual
 Meeting of the Air & Waste Management Association, Denver, CO.  June 13-18, 1993.
                                         59

-------
 EPA. 19935. "National Water Quality Inventory: 1992 Report to Congress. "Draft report. EPA
 Office of Water.  July 1993.


 EPA. 1993c.  "Review of Program Costs in Part 2  NPDES Municipal  Storm Water Permit
 Applications." Draft report. EPA Office of Water.  August, 1993.


 EPA. 1993d.  "Report to Congress on Storm Water Dischargers Not Regulated Under Phase I
 of the NPDES Storm Water Program." Draft report. November, 1993.


 EPA. 1993e. "Guidance Specifying Management Measures for Sources of Nonpoint Pollution
 in Coastal Waters." 840-B-92-002. EPA Office of Water.  January 1993.


 EPA. 1993f.  "State Program Costs for Implementing the Federal Clean Water Act "  EPA
 Office of Water.   December 6, 1993.


 EPA. 1994. "CWA Benefits of Nonpoint Source Controls." EPA background paper. January
 EPA. 1994a.  "Costs and Benefits Related to Groundwater Provisions of the Green Book. " EPA
 Office of Water background paper. January 1994.


 EPA.  1994b. "CWA Benefits of Mitigation of Inactive and Abandoned Mines on Federal
 Lands."  EPA background paper.  January 1994.

 EPA. 1994c.  "Detailed Cost Estimates for Storm Water." EPA Office of Water.     January
 1994.


 EPA. 1994d.  "Summary of CSO Costs and Benefits of Various CSO Controls " EPA Office
 of Water. January 18, 1994.


 EPA.  1994e.  "CWA Benefits of Storm Water Controls." EPA background paper   January
 1994.                                                                           3


 EPA.  1994f.  "CWA Benefits of Toxic Controls."  EPA Office of Watr background paper
 January 1994.


 EPA.  1994g.  "CWA Benefits of a Watershed Protection Approach."  EPA Office of Water
 background paper.  January 1994.


EPA.  1994h.  "Aggregate Economic Benefits for Controlling Selected Urban-Based Pollution
Sources."  February 1994.


ERG.  1993.   "Documentation of Costs  of NPS Control  Under  Reauthorized CWA."
Memorandum from Jeff Cantin, ERG,  to Mark Luttner, EPA Office of Water.  December 22,
                                       60

-------
1993.
16, 1993. (206-649-7180).
Lyon R and S. Farrow. 1992.  "An Economic Analysis of Clean Water Act Issues: Preliminary
Results." Office of Management and Budget. February 1992.

Metcalf & Eddy. 1993.  " 1992 CSO Needs Survey: Technical Report on the Estimation of CSO
Needs." Draft report. September 29,  1993.
Mitchell R C and R.T. Carson. 1984. "Willingness to Pay for National Freshwater Quality
Improvements."  CR 810224-01. EPA, Washington, D. C.

Mitchell RC and R.T. Carson. 1986. "The Use of Contingent Valuation Data for Benefit/Cost
      * in Water Pollution Control."  CR 810224-02. EPA, Washington, D. C.
Nicoll, D. 1994. Personal communication between Debra Nicoll, Office Water, and Jeff Cantin,
ERG. January 1994.
NOAA  1993. Personal communication between Bess Gillelan, US .Department «f Commerce
National Oceanographic and Atmospheric Administration, and Jim Pendergast, EPA Office of
Water.  November 15, 1993.
Phillips et al  1993. "The Effects of Alternative Pulping and Bleaching Processes on Product
Performance'   Economic  and Environmental Concerns." In  Prom»dWs:  International
           nn pST^ntion in the Manufacture, of Pulp and Paper - Opportunities and
          m nn                                    ,
          ITust 180,  1992.  EPA-744R-93-002,.  EPA Office of Pollution Prevention and
  Toxics.  February 1993.
            r Bailly  1992.  "Regulatory Impact Analysis: Management Measures Guidance for
             ^toS. in Coastal Watershed Areas."   Prepared for the Nonpomt Source
  Control Branch, EPA/OW/OWOW.  December 28, 1992.
  Strand I 1993  "The Contribution of Clean Water to Commercial Fisheries." In  Proceedings
  !S^n w^nd ft- *™— " *™n«mv Conference. EPA 800-R-93-001a. Washington, D.
  C.
  USDA  1994  "Impacts of Selected Clean Water Provisions on the Agricultural Sector. "Letter
  fromtohn Stierna, U.S. Department of Agriculture, Soil Conservation Service, toMarkLuttner,
  EPA Office of Water. January 24, 1994.
                                           61

-------

-------
                                          Table 1

                         Classification of Nonpoint Source Sectors
NFS Sector

Agriculture
 Forestry
 Urban areas
  Hydromodification
  Marinas

  Wetlands, riparian areas, and
    vegetated treatment systems
Soil erosion from cultivated cropland
Annual grazing, espcially in streamside areas
Management of nutrient applications
Control of irrigation flows
Animal waste management
Pre-harvest planning
Streamside management  areas
Forest road construction/reconstruction
Timber harvesting
Site preparation and forest regeneration
Fire management
Revegetation of disturbed areas
Management of forest chemical use
Management of forest wetland areas
 Construction site runoff
 Developing areas runoff
 Existing; development runoff
 On-site sewage disposal systems
 Road/highway/bridge runoff
 Household/commercial/landscaping waste disposal
 Channelization and channel  modification
 Dam construction and maintenance
 Shore erosion
 Marina siting and design
 Operation and maintenance practices

 Protection of wetlands  and riparian areas
  Restoration of wetlands and riparian areas
  Use of constructed wetlands, filter strips, buffer strips
                                                                 ures for Sources of Nonpoint
                                                      of Water, January 1993.

-------
g

-------
                                    Table 3

             Descriptive Statistics of the Coastal and Noncoastal Z-one
       Statistic
=	
 Counties (1990)
	•	•—
 Population (1990)
	.	•	
 Land area - sq. mi.
 (1990)
       ——
 Surface water area
 sq. mi.  (1990)

 Farms (1987)
 _	
  Farm land - acres
  (1987)
 Total U.S.

      3,130
     ^_^—^—^—^—
246,750,237

  3,521,131

   	
     241,151



   2,081,085
  __————
 958,775,957
Coastal Zone
        ==
         678
        ^~~^—
 127,351,147
    •
     635,166

     _       ~~
     122,402
                                                        Noncoastal
                                                              Zone
      2,452
119,399,090
  2,885,965
    118,749
      405,844 I     1,675,241
   98,677,897 I   860,098,060
                                              Noncoastal
                                                Zone as
                                              Percent of
                                                   Total
  Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, USA Coupes (CD-ROM).

-------
                                                                                         8
         Is
I
                                                                                                   s
                                                                                                  oo
                                                                                                  I
  o
  ,0

  2
  "3
                                                                                                        I
                                                                                                         s
          S
          o
                                                                                                        •s
                                                                                                         bo
                                                                                                        03
  |     IB

  Z     a
  w     s
  O     lH
  u     u,
 *-•«     o
  ca    <*-<
  3     
-------
I/I

-------


-------

-------

-------
 o>
1

-------
:§
a

-------
1
&

-------
                                       Table 12

   Summary of Likelihood That Full Implementation of NPS Management Measures Will
                 Measurably Improve National Water Quality1 - Rivei

                             Likelihood of Achieving Measurable Water Quality Improvement
                                           in 10 to 20 Years (Miles)
1 Projected for 54 states and territories based on WBS analysis.

-------
S
 0)

1


                       I
                       o


                       o
                       *—I
                       .a
                       s
 I
                       3
s
 60
                       1
I
                             a
                             CO

                                                           oo
                                                           00
                                    s
                                              vo
                                              oo
g
po
                                    PL,
OTAL

-------
                                    Table 14
  Summary of Likelihood That Full Implementation of NFS Management Measures Will
                Measurably Improve National Water Quality1 - Lakes
Use Support Status
Fully Supporting but
Threatened
Partially Supporting
Not Supporting
TOTAL
Likelihood of Achieving Measurable Water Quality Improvement
in 10 to 20 Years (Acres)
High
1,026,355
0
0
1,026,355
Medium
1,288,996
4,799,150
13,736
6,101,882
Low
0
1,447,097
1,588,298
3,035,395
1 Projected for 54 states and territories based on WBS analysis.

-------











3
o
1
1
-a
o
U

CM
0
v> JS
iH !S
3 S
,Q O>
s w
H -d
id
ce



u
S
u
'S
1
a
H
00









J
|H
z o
<: u
















iNEFITS
PQ







j
O ^
O P*
Pf S
!z '""'
O w
?£
PQ 2^
w CD
i-J CL,

rt H
•a .— i tg
«a£


co

2 42 *t
1*1 $

00
r^ ^5
II i
S On 04

8
CH W *>
.2 "S o
»— < S &
'*£ <£ fS


Number of
Days WQS
Violated





Number of
Untreated
Overflows



i!
fl
e- s




1 1 03
t-i 
S,
WH
S

>o
2 •
_t 0^
« t~
o O
§ ' 1
« J_»
&• w
J> «
o P
<3 S
« E
3 .S
§ §
1 *
5 1
•3 S,
.w O
S M
is a
2 * » -1
"8 1 "S -3 °
^ « § § "S
t-l i 1 1
*1 o 1 i
•S o 2 § |
ft ^~* '^ en w
1= 3 -a J
w s? s "o a
1» | H 'I-
•S § | 8 o
^- i 1 i
i^ 1 1 i
s2 8 8 o
ea fw \J
c c -S c e
= 1 Q w —

u M" W H 'S<
1 1 ° o S
« g 60 60 .g
"5 « « a "§
o * -S & -S
C *0 F-< i—t «J
fS 1 1 1
o ° S c Z
*t 1 1 1
?l 1 2 1
-• O 04 « *

-------
  DC
'co H-
0) ro
J= C
s|

O CO
— CD
co *i
.£ =
'o *~
00 ^
00 S
OO'T-
co
<»



CO
a.
DC
f-
"co
o

^
•a
CO
o
4^
o
CD
15"
co
2
CD
co
."co
to
D
•o




CO
^*
O
0-
*-"
0)
CO
CD
£
a.
o
o
in
»-
CO




o
CD
a.
E
•a
to
a.
o
CD
CD
T3
ic2
E<
*-• E
co 1—
<-• "5
5§
t* "*"*
pi
a. co














CM
00
CN
•CO-











?
       co


       I
       o

       CD
      JZ
                                                                                     CO

                                                                                     CD
                                                                                    JD
                                                                                     CD
                                                                                     +->
                                                                                     CO
                                                                                    •a
                                                                                     CD
                                                                                     CO
                                                                                     CO
                                                                                     CO

                                                                              .2     CD
 CO

_co

 a.
                                                                                     CD

                                                                                     co
                                                                                     CD
                                                                                     O
 O

'•5
 co     5

 c     o
.2     w
 O     CD

•3     I

 2    -^
 o     a-

 I     ro  „:
 f    $  |

 CO     CD  CO
Q-     *2  Sz.

-------
                                    Table 17
Summary of Aggregate Annualized Costs from Control of Urban Sources Under the
Initiative and Pending Spending (CSOs, Storm Water, Toxics)
Cost Category
Municipal Costs
Phase I Storm water
Phase II Storm water
CSO Controls
CZARA Non-Point Controls
Pending Spending (Great Lakes,
Sludge)
Subtotal Municipal
Private Sector
Phase I Storm water
Phase II Storm water
Pollution Prevention Plans
Domestic Sewage Exclusion
Nonpoint Source Controls
Subtotal Private Sector
Total Quantified Costs in Urban Areas
Range:: Low - High
(Millions of 1993 $)
$ 1,650 - $ 2,555
$ 1,030- $ 1,910
$ 3,450
$ 390 - $ 590
$90
$ 6,610 - $ 8,595
$2,360- $2,850
$ 345 - $ 1,670
$ 60 - $ 120
$280
$ 233 - $ 388
$ 3,278 - $ 5,308
$ 9,888 - $ 13,903
Non-Quantified Costs
State Administration Costs (Urban portion of $650m)
Federal Compliance (Urban portion of $945m) - excludes abandoned mines.
Groundwater Controls (Urban portion of $150m to $600m)
Further Water Quality Criteria and Standards and sediment criteria
Toxics Bans
Other Pending Spending (e.g., Great Lakes, Pulp and Paper Effluent Guidelines, Air
MACT standards)
Source: Summary of Tables 19 and 20

-------
                                            Table 18
Summary of Aggregate Annualized Benefits from Control of Urban Sources Under the
Initiative and Pending Spending (CSOs, Storm Water, Toxics)
                            Benefit Category
                                         Quantified Benefits
Range: Low - High
(Millions of 1993 $)
Freshwater Recreational Fishing and Swimming (use and nonuse)
Marine Recreational Fishing (use only)
Marine Nonconsumptive Recreation (use only)
Marine and Freshwater Commercial Fishing
Withdrawal or Diversionary Uses
Human Health Effects (from risks associated with exposure to pollutants via
1 swimming activity and seafood consumption)1
1 Sub-total: Quantified Benefits2
I Assuming immediate attainment of benefits3
(i) Annualized Benefits (no lag and no discounting, thus a
simple summation of individual categories)
Assuming a gradual attainment of benefits over the first 15 year period that
all Urban Source Controls are adopted.*
; (ii) Annualized Benefits (seven percent discount rate, gradual
attainment over first 15 years)
(iii) Annualized benefits (three percent discount rate, gradual
attainment over first 15 years)
$ 650 - $ 4,670
$ 40 - $ 440
$ 30 - $ 300
$ 40 - $ 190
$ 20 - $ 80
$ 40 - $ 320
(i) $ 820 - $ 6,000
(ii) $560 -$4,100
(iii) $ 660 - $ 4,900
Non-Quantified Benefits
- Marine Recreational Swimming (nonhealth effects)
- Other Human Health Effects in Marine and Freshwaters (see Note 1)
- Recreational Hunting- Freshwater Nonconsumptive Recreation (see Note 1)
- Marine Recreational Boating
- Other Non-use Benefits (Marine Waters - see Note 1)
- Other avoided costs (e.g., water storage, dredging, damages from floods).
- Restoration of biodiversity and ecosystem integrity.
 Given information and methods used to calculate the quantified benefits, some portion of the benefits associati
with these categories may be captured in the monetary range ascribed to freshwater recreation fishing and
swimming.
2 Assumes no double counting of benefits or substitution effects between different categories when developing
aggregate national estimates. Also assumes that all upper ends of the range for each quantified category describe
the aggregate lower and upper bound estimate.  Absent information on the distribution or probability of attaining
benefits defined by the estimated range, we can not calculate a "most likely" estimate.
3 Assuming no lag between implementation of controls, recovery of natural ecological systems, and economic
behavior that forms the basis for the economic benefit measures.
4 These estimates of the economic benefits  are more appropriate to use when comparing quantified costs and
benefits, given the anticipated lag time between introduction of the control measures and  full realization of the
environmental and economic benefits. The calculated annualized figure is based on assuming a gradual attainment
of benefits up through year fifteen, and a constant future benefits stream after the fifteenth year has been reached.

-------
I


-1
rs


-•*
° c
u 5
**
State Water
Programs1
§

3
O
•c
^

s
1


II
II





Provisions


i
ci
69



"J.
ON"
69
§


ON
i- 1



O
ON
69


i
i





Pre-1987 Act

ON
3
00
oo
o\



en
69

B
cn



eg
69

ON
1
00






"8
0 _C
2 S
Nonpoint Sou:
Controls/wate
in
•*
n
6^
1
V*












!R
3
i
o
69

1
3

o
rt
y^

2
CO


8
•*_














o
5









EA
O
CO
O

2

T-4
8
69













00
00
69

P
0.
T-H
5
o\




CA
O
U
1
ON
O
a
69
1
cn
s
69
oo
p.
oC
69
1
69
1
69


i-H
69
00
§
I

€^
1
o
cn
69
ON
T— 1
i




TOTALS
                                          I
                                          t
                                          8
                                          «
                                          8

-------
>!
H §

"3 •§
1 ^



State Water
Programs
g
3
1

.8
£3
1
a
s

Private
Sources







Provisions
8
>n
8"
1
23
o
oo
v-l
t— 1
69

69
O
69
in
,_,
fl
3
1 S

fi-R

oo
oo
en
i
en
69





|i
INonpoint Sou
Controb/watei
i
o\
3
0\
69







O

,_^
69

*»
O
$
T-)
1
CO

1
S
<^

60
*c

-3
1
|| Pollution Prev
„
69

















00


c
.2
M
a
1
o
Domestic Sew
l-H
1

8
en



00
00
V-H










s






M
NPDES & W(
00







00
















•£»
O
I
SRF/Construc
00
69


Si



00
T— t


















Monitoring
§
o
en
69
8
T-H
i-H
1
O
CO
12
^


















1
Abandoned M
.
69


£





















I
Department o)
oo
"V
oT
i
g
8
i— i
i
3

*
69
VO
1—1
1
io
1

§
cS
§

z
0

-------
I

*3
3
n






2 1>
I i
fe 2
11
t
&
o
1
1

c

s


B §>

^ 3
'£ 5





Provisions

VI
s
1
v>










00
v»
1
T— (














OS
"8
82
INonpoint Sour
Controls/Wate:
of

69 69
§8
T-H_ CO_

69 <-H
69











%
69
i
>n
v>
t--
69
o
o o\
5" 12
69 69
i I
§8
«-T •*"
69 -H
69


Storm Water:
Phase I
Phase II


o'














§
o"
tf.













VI


oo
CO
69





CO
00
69

o
CO
69


















O
1
Discharge Fee!

00
co"
69
CO
s.



t-H
00

8"
i






















i
Abandoned Mi
§

i
00
s
oT

69
3
>n
8
\o
CO
1-H

g
8
00
0
1
d>
&<
2
u
2
•o
C
(9
2
c
•i

I


-------
a ^

                II
o o

38


853
   V)
                                                                      §
                                                               8
                                                   S
                                          in Q
                                          m vo
                                          m r-


                                          88
                                          o m
                                          in oo
                                                                        in


                                                                        3?
                                                                        $
Co
                                                                                    o-<
                                                                                    o
                                                                                    2
                                                                                    w
                                                                                    CO

                                                                                    S3
                                            g
                                           CO

-------
                                             Fiigure 1

                       Nonpoint Source Management Measures Applied
                                       in Benefits Analysis
 Agriculture
Urban Runoff
Construction
Erosion and Sediment Control
Facility Wastewater and Runoff
from Confined Animal Facility
Management  (Large and Small
Units not permitted under
NPDES)
Nutrient Management
Pesticide Management
Grazing Management
Irrigation Water Management

Preharvest Planning
Streamside Management Areas
Road Construction/Reconstruction
Road Management
Timber Harvesting
Site Preparation and Forest
Regeneration
Fire Management
Revegetation of Disturbed Areas
Forest Chemical Management
Wetlands Forest Management

New Development
Watershed Protection
Site Development
                                                     Channelization and Channel Modification
                                                             >      Physical and Chemical
                                                                    Characteristics of Surface Waters
                                                             >      Instream and Riparian Habitat
                                                                    Restoration
                                                     Streambank and Shoreline Erosion
                                                             »•      Eroding Streambanks and
                                                                    Shorelines
                                                     Wetlands. Riparian Areas, and Vegetated
                                                     Treatment Systems
                                                             >      Protection of Wetlands and
                                                                    Riparian Areas
                                                             *      Restoration of Wetlands and
                                                                    Riparian Areas
                                                             >      Vegetated Treatment Systems
        >      Construction Site Erosion and
               Sediment Control
        >      Construction Site Chemical
               Control
Existing Development
        >      Existing Development
Pollution Prevention
        >      Pollution Prevention
Roads. Highways, and Bridges
        >      Planning, Siting, and Developing
               Roads and Highways
        >      Bridges
        f-      Construction Projects
        >      Construction Site Chemical
        >      Operation and Maintenance
        >      Road, Highway, and Bridge
               Runoff Systems

-------

M
w


O
E
   I
    c
    o
   o
43
C
V
CO

•o
    V)
    O
    u
                   I*
                  45i
                                       .i ~
                                           HI

HI
"HI
HI
<•
O
•»*
E
.jj
e
'••
-e
1
HI
M
I
O
"o
-e
o -
Q
«
•HI -
n
HI
•9> -
                                                       HI


                                                       '
                                            1 Hi !1 !i
                                              \  *l  |i lL
                                              I  •*  i' I4

-------
APPENDICES

-------

-------
                                                                  APPENDIX A
                             Nonpoint Source Case Studies

 Selected case studies were identified to gauge the validity of the analytic results, and to illustrate
 the significance and specifics of study findings.  These case studies were selected to correspond
 with the prevalent combinations of sources and pollutants to the extent possible. Case studies
 were found for agriculture, forestry, urban, and hydromodification.

 (a) Agricultural Case Studies:

 Seiders, K. 1993. "Moxie Drain BMP Implementation Demonstration Project Water Quality
 Monitoring Report." Washington State Department of Ecology.  September 1993.

 This 2-year project in the Moxie Drain watershed demonstrated the benefits of implementing a
 sediment  settling basin,  irrigation system  retrofits (valves, piping,  sprinkler heads,  etc.),
 irrigation water management, reduced tillage, and furrow mulching.  These practices, which are
 similar to the irrigation and erosion management measures, were implemented on 87% of the
 irrigated land.

 Water  quality improvements at the study site included median pollutant reductions for total
 suspended solids (TSS) (86%),  TSS load (90%), Imhoff Settleable Solids (99%), nephelometric
 turbidity (63%), absorbtometric turbidity (75%), ammonia (56%), and ammonia load (60%).
 Much of the improvement was due to climatic factors, but data from a reference watershed were
 used to show that the best management practices (BMPs) improved water quality.

 Gunsalus,  B., E.G. Flaig, and G. Ritter. 1992. "Effectiveness of Agricultural Best Management
 Practices Implemented in the Taylor Creek/Nubbin Slough Watershed and the Lower Kissimmee
 River  Basin."   In: The National Rural Clean Water Program Symposium:  10 years of
 Controlling Agricultural Nonpoint Source Pollution: The RCWP Experience.  EPA Office of
 Water.

 Implementation of animal  waste  collection and nutrient recycling  systems  similar  to  the
 management  measures  for confined  animal facilities and  nutrient management  caused a
 significant decrease in the median total phosphorus concentrations at most sites in this dairy area.
 Median total phosphorus concentration values decreased by 84 percent,  and phosphorus load
decreased by 40 percent in the  basin.

Nevada. "Restoring the Quinn River, An Important Riparian Resource."  Draft  of EPA Section
319 Success Stories.  September 30, 1993.

Using techniques similar to the grazing management measure, a riparian pasture was fenced to
control the amount, timing, and location of grazing, and to allow the riparian area of the East
                                         A-l

-------
Fork Quinn River to recover from the impacts of poor grazing practices.  Implementation also
included streambank stabilization measures, such as the planting of juniper and sagebrush to slow
the velocity of water and the planting of 1,700 willows to reduce thermal pollution.

Monitoring showed thebioconcentration index (BCI) climbed from poor to fair due to the BMPs.
Habitat parameters such as bank cover, bank soil stability, and bank vegetation stability have
also improved over 5 years.

Oklahoma. "BMPs Reduce Nutrients in Battle Branch Watershed."  Draft of EPA Section 319
Success Stories.  September 30, 1993.

Waste management plans, poultry composters, and waste storage ponds were implemented by
84 percent of landowners in this 36,000-acre poultry and dairy watershed. These practices are
addressed in the confined animal facility management measures.  As a result of implementing
these BMPs,  nitrate levels during runoff have decreased by as  much as  72 percent and total
phosphorus levels by as much as 35 percent.

The following paragraphs were taken from EPA's "Guidance Specifying Management Measures
For Sources of Nonpoint Pollution in Coastal Waters."

In many instances landowners can actually save money by implementing  nutrient management
plans. For example, Maryland has estimated (based on the over 750 nutrient management plans
that were completed prior to September 30, 1990) that if plan recommendations are followed,
the landowners  will save an average of $23 per acre per year  (Maryland. Department of
Agriculture, 1990). The average savings may be high because most plans were for farms using
animal waste. Future savings may be reduced as more farms using commercial fertilizer are
included in the program.

In the South Dakota Rural Clean Water Program (RCWP) project, the total cost (1982-1991) for
implementing fertilizer management on 46,571 acres was $50,109,  or $1.08 per acre (USDA-
ASCS, 1991a). In the Minnesota RCWP project, the average cost for fertilizer management for
 1982-1988 was  $20 per acre (Wall et al., 1989).  Assuming a cost of $0.15 per pound of
nitrogen, the savings in fertilizer cost due to improved nutrient management of Iowa corn was
about $2.25 per acre as rates dropped from 145 pounds per acre in 1985 to about 130 pounds
per acre in 1989 and 1990 (Iowa State University, 199la).

Magleby, R., J. Kasal, D.  Walker, R. Gum. 1989.  "The Economics of  Controlling Sediment
 from Irrigation:  An Idaho Example." Report No. AGES 89-33. USDA,  ERS.

This project  addresses irrigated agriculture in the Rock Creek,  Idaho, RCWP Project. This
project implemented many of the practices addressed  in  the  erosion  and irrigation water
 management measures including conservation tillage and irrigation  water management (IWM).
 IWM follows the basic principle of the irrigation management measure by controlling the amount
 of water applied, rather than constructing expensive irrigation systems.  Both practices reduce
                                         A-2

-------
 production costs below those of conventional systems and produce a net cost savings or benefit
 to the farmer. The change in annualized cost per acre for conservation tillage is a savings of
 $33.00 compared with conventional tillage; for IWM the savings is  $4.50 compared with dirt-
 ditch irrigation.

 Hall, D., and D. Risser. 1992. "Effects of Nutrient Management on Nitrogen Flux through a
 Karst Aquifer, Conestoga  River Headwaters Basin, Pennsylvania." In: The National Rural
 Clean Water Program  Symposium:  10 years of Controlling Agricultural Nonpoint Source
 Pollution: The RCWP Experience. EPA Office of Water.

 This RCWP project studied the effects of nutrient management on  groundwater quality at an
 agricultural field site. Nutrient management, and the nutrient management measure, will in most
 cases result in reduced applications of manure and fertilizer to fields.  Analysis of pre- and post-
 nutrient management periods for groundwater  samples  resulted in statistically  significant
 decreases in  median nitrate concentrations at four of the five wells tested.

 "Public Rangelands: Some Riparian Areas Restored But Widespread Improvement Will Be
 Slow." GAO Report/RCED-88-105. June 1988.

 In Oregon, Bear Creeks' riparian areas were heavily overgrazed, causing the creek to dry up in
 the  summer.  After a new cattle management system resembling  the  grazing management
 measure, the riparian area was greatly improved.  The permittee stated that he cut his yearly
 feed costs by $10,000 as his AUMs increased from 75 to 400 in 1993.

 (b)  Forestry Case Studies:

 Curtis,  J.G.   et al. 1990.   "Effectiveness of Best  Management  Practices in  Preventing
 Degradation of Streams  Caused by Silvicultural Activities in Pickett  State Forest."  Tennessee
 Technological University for the Tennessee Department of Conservation.

 Three stands of timber in Tennessee had BMPs implemented prior to,  during, and after harvest.
 The BMPs applied  generally conformed to the  forestry management measures from the  (g)
 Guidance.  Monitoring was conducted before, during, and after timber harvest activities and
 showed that the timber harvest had no apparent detrimental impact on the adjacent streams.

 Lynch and Corbett.  1990. "Evaluations of Best Management Practices for Controlling Nonpoint
 Pollution From Silvicultural Operations." Water Resources Bulletin 26(1): 41-52.

 In the Leading Ridge  Watershed  in Pennsylvania,  BMPs were employed to control NPS
pollution.  The BMPs used, such as buffer strips, design of skid trails and roads, and preharvest
planning, closely followed the forestry management measures.  Monitoring results indicate that
the BMPs were effective in minimizing increases in turbidity, with no  major increases observed
during or immediately following cutting.
                                        A-3

-------
Swank, W.T. et al.  1989.  "Effects of Timber Management Practices on Soil and Water." In:
The Scientific Basis for Silvicultural and Management Decisions in the National Forest System.
R.M. Burns, ed.  General Technical Report WO-55.  USDA Forest Service, pp. 79-106.

This paper discusses the effects of BMPs, including BMPs addressed in the forestry management
measures.  The general effect on soil and water are discussed, along with the effects of BMPs
in different  forest types.   The three water  quality characteristics  most affected by timber
harvesting are sediment, dissolved nutrients,  and water temperature.   The paper stated that
providing buffer strips-or "streamside management areas," as it is called  in the guidance-can
mitigate the negative impact on these water quality characteristics.

The following paragraph was taken from EPA's "Guidance Specifying Management Measures
For Sources of Nonpoint Pollution in Coastal Waters" and illustrates the economic benefits of
preharvest planning.

A cost-benefit analysis by Dissmeyer and others (USDA,  1987) reveals the dramatic, immediate
savings from considering water quality during  the design phase of a road reconstruction project
(Table A-l).  Expertise on soil and water protection provided by a hydrologist resulted in  50
percent of the savings alone.  Other long-term economic benefits of careful planning such as
longer road life and reduced maintenance costs were not quantified in this analysis.
         Table A-1. Costs and Benefits of Proper Road Design (With Water Quality Considerations)
                     Versus Reconstruction (Without Water Quality Considerations)
                                  (USDA Forest Service, 1987)	
                                           Without Soil/ Water
                                                 Input0
With Soil/Water Input8
Miles of road
Reconstruction costs
Soil/water input costs
Immediate benefit (savings) of
soil/water input
3.0
$796,000
-
-

3.0
$372,044
$800
$211,978

          Soil/water inputs are design adjustments made by a hydrologist and include narrower road width and
          steeper road bank cuts in soils of low credibility and low revegetation potential.
                                            A-4

-------
  (c) Urban case studies:

  Bath Club Concourse Storm Water Rehabilitation project, Tampa Bay, Florida

  BMP:  Porous Pavement

  Benefits: Reduced loadings to Boca Ciega Bay
 Hollywood, South Carolina (Success Stories, page 35)

 BMP: Rock/Plant onsite disposal system for wastewater

 Benefits:  95% fecal coliform removal,  85%  BOD treatment, 65% TSS treatment  10% N
 removal - predicted removal rates 80-90%
 Boulder Creek, Colorado, TMDL Case Study

 BMPs: Cattle exclusions/crossings, streambank stabilization log revetments, riparian zone willow
 and cottonwood plantings, replacement of channelized berms with sculpted streambanks, channel
 modification (thalweg pools), wetland enhancement, and boulder aeration structures.

 Benefit:  Successful improvement of instream conditions
 Fourche Creek, Alaska, National Urban Runoff Program (NURP)

 BMPs:  Retention basins, rip-rap and vegetation, grass planting and sodding, reduced slopes,
 check dams, grassed  drainage or overflow areas,  gabions and channel  clearing with bank
 relocation

 Benefits: Loading reductions from BMP implementation

 Expected benefits: Improved parks and recreational systems in several disadvantaged and
 minority neighborhoods; improvements of Fourche Creek waters to meet water quality standards-
 reductions of health hazards from contact and fishing                                    '
Jordon River Parkway Demonstration Project, Utah
(§319 Success Stories:  Cost: $150,000)

BMPs: Streambank stabilization including rip-rap and vegetative stabilization, slope grading and
wetland pond systems
                                        A-5

-------
Benefits: Decreased  concentrations of arsenic, zinc,  TSS, DO, nitrate and phosphorus; park
enhancement, flourishing riparian vegetation (trees, shrubs, wildflowers, and grasses), wetland
plant communities
Lake Barcroft, Virginia (Natural Lawn, personal communication, 1991)

BMP:  Use of low-phosphate and phosphate-free fertilizers

Benefit:  Estimated 7,000-pound loading reduction in fall P loadings, and 80-85% decrease in
spring loadings to the lake
Anacostia River Case Study  (Converse example)

Retrofitting example to illustrate high costs of remediating system

The Anacostia watershed is predominantly residential/commercial and is not dominated by
industrial discharges.  Estimated capital cost for structural BMPs identified in the restoration
plan is $27.6 million without adding planning, design, permitting and land acquisition costs.
Stream restoration and reforestation costs will incur additional costs of at least $800,000 to the
restoration effort. (Anacostia Watershed Restoration Committee, 1992)
 Alternative example consistent with CZAR §6217(g) Guidance
 Woodlands, Texas.  "Design With Nature."  Sykes, R. 1989. Chapter 3.1, Minnesota Pollution
 Control Agency Handbook, "Protecting Water Quality in Urban Areas."

 BMPs: Site planning, minimization of impervious surface, protection of natural drainageway,
 grassed swales

 Benefits: $14 million was saved by  the developer by selecting natural drainage/vegetative
 retention systems instead of conventional storm water management systems for water quantity
 and quality controls when designing the site.

 (d) Hydromodification case study:

 Chesapeake Bay Shoreline Erosion study, U.S. Corps  of Engineers, States of Maryland and
 Virginia

 BMPs: Revetments, groins, bulkheads, vegetative stabilization

                                           A-6

-------
        (erosion reduction ranges from 30 to 100%)

Benefits: Water-oriented recreation,  land loss prevention, property damage prevention, and loss
of access protection,  water quality protection, and habitat protection (sediment control).  The
elimination of sediment was estimated to increase productivity 20%. Bay wide benefits total $15
million for level 1 and $9 million for level 2.
                                     References

EPA. 1992.  "Managing  Nonpoint Source Pollution."  EPA-506/9-90.   Office of Water,
Washington, D. C.

Clausen, J.C., D.W. Meals,  and E.A. Cassell. 1992. "Estimation of Lag Time for Water
Quality  Response to BMPS."  In: Seminar Publication - The National Rural Clean Water
Program Symposium.   EPA/625/R-92/006.   Office of Research and Development/Office of
Water, Washington, D. C.

Rosa, F. 1987.  "Lake Erie Central Basin Total Phosphorus Trend Analysis From 1968 to
1982."  J. Great Lakes  Res.  13(4): 667-673.

Hallberg, G.R., R.D. Libra, Zhi-Jun Liu, R.D. Rowden, and K.D. Rex. 1993. "Watershed-
Scale Water-Quality  Response  To Changes in Landuse  and  Nitrogen Management."  In:
Proceedings of Agricultural Research to Protect Water Quality.  February 21-24,1993. Soil and
Water Conservation Society, Ankeny, IA.
                                        A-7

-------
           CWA Benefits Under CZARA Management Scenario

Ecosystem protection.  Maintain water body current status.  The costs of streambank
stabilization, hardening of conveyances, and wetlands remediation can be decreased or
eliminated.  Prevention or reduction of habitat destruction due to physical alteration of
water quality and quantity, sedimentation, scouring,  and flooding.

Protection of property  values,  e.g.,  loss  of fasfland  and  streambank  property.
Enhancement of property values as a result of riparian buffer protection or restoration.
Increased property value due to proximity to aesthetically pleasing storm water treatment
systems such as  constructed wetlands.

Protection of fisheries and estuarine incubators and spawning areas. (Economic data may
be available from NOAA on commercial fishers adversely impacted by NPS.)

Protection of water oriented recreational values.

Reduction of water costs by the use of low-flow plumbing fixtures; high quality water-
efficient plumbing  fixtures can reduce  50%  of residential water use and wastewater
volume, with resulting savings in water bills and corresponding decreases in wastewater
treatment costs.

Reduce pesticide and fertilizer costs.  Education programs for proper lawn care, turf
management, and xeriscaping programs can reduce residential and commercial fertilizer,
pesticide, and water costs and associated pollutant loadings.  Pesticide loadings can be
reduced 85-90 percent where spot applications are substituted for blanket applications
depending on site specific conditions.  Northern Virginia Soil and Water Conservation
District estimated that two-thirds less fertilizer can be applied to residential lawns than
commonly recommended by manufacturers.   Such practices  could result in nitrogen
loading reductions of up to 50%.

Protect and improve groundwater and surface water quality by reducing nitrogen loadings
to groundwater and water bodies. Use of denitrifying Onsite Disposal Systems (OSDS)
can significantly reduce nitrogen loadings to groundwater.  (Chesapeake Bay studies
indicate that 55-85% of the nitrogen  loadings to OSDS  system can pass directly to
groundwater and hydrologically connected surface waters.)

Phosphorus loading reductions and cost  savings from the elimination of phosphate
detergents.  Estimated savings  of $1.8  to $2.8 million in POTW costs.
                                    A-8

-------
                                                                  APPENDIX B
                      STORM AND SURFACE WATER UTILITY
                             BELLEVUE, WASHINGTON

       Bellevue, Washington, is a suburban community located in the Puget Sound area east of
 Lake Washington in the Seattle metropolitan area. The city experienced substantial population
 growth during the last 30 years and particularly rapid growth over the last 20 years.  When
 Bellevue incorporated as a city in 1953, the population was approximately 6,000 and the city
 limits covered five square miles.  By 1990, Bellevue had grown to a population of 86,000 and
 an area  that covered 30  square miles, making it the fourth largest city in Washington State.
 Recent estimates indicate that  the watershed is over 90 percent developed,  primarily with
 residential units and commercial and light industrial uses.

       Rapid growth and development created  storm water runoff problems in most of the
 natural streams draining the area.  The city's 30-square mile area contains over 50 miles of open
 streams and five lakes. Much of the average annual rainfall of 42 inches is carried by existing
 streams  into the following receiving waters: Kelsey Creek, Meydenbauer Bay and the Lake
 Washington East Channel, Yarrow Bay on Laike Washington, Lake Sammamish, and Coal
 Creek. Of these, Lake Washington is considered the primary receiving water body.  The types
 of storm water runoff problems documented in the Bellevue area include increased flooding and
 streambank erosion; property damage; stream sedimentation/siltation; diminished salmon runs;
 water quality degradation by discharges of nutrients, heavy metals, pesticides, and oil; and illicit
 connections.

       In response to citizen concerns about environmental degradation caused by storm water
 runoff, the city of Bellevue established a storm water utility in 1974. The mission of Bellevue's
 Storm and  Surface Water Utility (SSWU) is to manage the storm and surface water system in
 Bellevue, to maintain a hydrologic balance, to prevent property damage, and to protect water
 quality for the safety and enjoyment of citizens and the preservation and enhancement of wildlife
 habitat.

 STORM AND SURFACE WATER UTILITY  PROGRAMS

       When first established, Bellevue's  utility focused  on examining various solutions to
 control flooding  and preserve waterways.  The utility selected an "open  stream concept" using
 streams as  the main  conveyance system for storm water runoff.   This  system uses regional,
in-stream flood control facilities to attenuate peal: flows for  older development.  The utility also
 manages the municipal  storm drainage system.  In addition, regulations require developers to
provide erosion  and  sedimentation controls at all construction sites and on-site storm water
controls for new development. With successful  flood control systems in place, the focus has
recently shifted to water quality controls, including requirements mandated by the federal Clean
Water  Act.  For the most part, SSWU's comprehensive effort to solve storm water quality
                                         B-l

-------
problems is preventive in nature, but the utility also recognizes the need for retrofitting and new
capital improvements for treatment.

       Management of Bellevue's storm drainage system and open streams involves five major
programs: a capital improvement program, operations and maintenance, water quality control,
public education, and administration.  Activities conducted under each of the major programs
are summarized below.

       •      Capital improvement program.  SSWU's capital improvement program (CIP)
              involves planning, design, property acquisition, flood control construction, water
              quality treatment,  and stream enhancement projects.  The utility constructed a
              series  of 11  in-stream flood control  facilities  (detention basins)  within the
              Bellevue stream system to provide protection for the 24-hour,  100-year storm
              event.  SSWU also improves stream passages for carrying capacity, stability,
              wildlife habitat, and migratory fish passage.

       •      Operations and maintenance. The operations and maintenance (O&M) program
              involves those functions typically associated with urban drainage, such as repair
              and minor replacement of SSWU's structural facilities. Bellevue's O&M program
              also includes operation of structures for flood control, including a telemetry
              control system  for structures and an  emergency storm response program, a
              drainage system inventory, and advice to  private citizens on private drainage
              concerns.

       •      Water quality control. Activities conducted for water control include drainage
              system cleaning, routine monitoring of receiving waters, investigative monitoring
              of pollution events and sources, emergency response for water pollution events,
              coordination with other water quality  control agencies,  participation  in lake
              restoration studies and projects, a private maintenance inspection program, and
              a streams enhancement program.

       •      Public education.  SSWU's public education efforts focus on available services
              and the environment.  Specific activities include articles  in  local publications
              about SSWU services and the effects of human practices on the environment, the
              Stream Team Program (includes  a  water quality newsletter, workshops, and
              citizen activities),  City Hall's  "Mini Salmon Hatchery" and  annual salmon
              release,  storm drain stenciling projects, and a business water quality program.

       •      Administration.    Administrative  programs  for  SSWU  include  financial
              management, rate administration,  comprehensive drainage  planning,  general
              administration, and support for the City Council and Storm and Surface Water
              Advisory Commission.  SSWU assures quality  control of utility services by
              tracking all service requests through an automated  Customer  Action Request
              system.
                                          B-2

-------
UTILITY FINANCING

       The city decided that the most equitable system of drainage service charges entails basing
changes on the estimated amount of runoff that individual properties contribute to the surface
water system. All properties are classified according to their intensity of development.  Each
classification is assigned a rate (per 2,000 square feet of property area), with current rates set
as follows: undeveloped  ($0.17), light development ($0.99), moderate development ($1.23),
heavy development ($1.83), and very heavy development ($2.46).  Wetlands are also a class;
however, wetlands are not charged due to their value in water quantity and quality control. The
classification combined with the total square footage of  the property determines the service
charge, which is billed every two months.

       Revenues grew  slowly until rates were raised to fund the adopted Capital Improvement
Program,  which was initiated by issuance of $10 million  in revenue bonds. Three major rate
increases  occurred in  1980  (70 percent), 1982  (90  percent), and 1986 (35 percent), and
subsequent rate increases have remained in the single-digit category largely to cover inflation.
Although the majority of SSWU revenue is from service charges, other revenue sources include
clearing and grading permit fees, general facilities charges, and interest on fund accounts.
Revenues from  the utility service  charges  and these other sources cover the full costs  of
Bellevue's storm and surface water  management program.

       Single-family customers make up 92 percent of the 24,000 accounts and contribute 45
percent of the revenue.  An average single-family household pays $16.44 every two months ($98
per year) for 10,000 to 12,000 square feet of property with a typical home.  Tax-exempt
properties are not exempt from the  utility charges. (Washington State highways and Bellevue
streets are the SSWU's two biggest ratepayers.)

BENEFITS OF THE  STORM  AND SURFACE WATER PROGRAM

       One of the most successful of SSWU's programs is flood control, and several different
approaches to managing storm water discharges are achieving water quality improvements.  In
addition, Bellevue's reputation as a well-planned, environmentally sensitive city is enhanced
through SSWU programs that preserve the city's numerous streams.

Reductions in Peak Flows

        •      Bellevue's use of the natural stream system to manage storm water preserves the
              environment and reduces costs. Bellevue's  storm water management activities to
              address  flooding and stream erosion problems range from four to ten times less
              costly than traditional storm sewer improvements.

        •      Small detention basins (detention times of 30 minutes; or less) reduced peak flow
              rates by up to 60 percent, providing flood and streambank erosion control that
              protects streamside property.
                                          B-3

-------
       •      With a computerized remote control system, maximum flood protection along
              major stream corridors is achieved through eight regional detention basins. The
              remote control system monitors rainfall, stream flow, and water levels to ensure
              optimal operation of flood gates to control peak flows.

       •      During a 100-year storm experienced by the Bellevue area in January  1986,
              property damages occurred only  where planned improvements  were not yet
              constructed. Capital improvements totalling $15 million and constructed over the
              previous 10 years reduced flooding and streambank erosion, thereby avoiding
              property damages.

       •      Calls for emergency service during storm events continue to decrease, indicating
              that SSWU's flood control system has significantly reduced  hazards to life and
              property.

Reductions in Pollutant Loadings/Discharges

       •      Runoff concentrations of lead and total solids were reduced by between 10 to 25
              percent over a two-year period through biannual cleaning of storm  drainage inlet
              sumps and catch basins. Chemical oxygen  demand (COD), nutrient, and zinc
              concentrations were reduced by between 5 to 10 percent over a two-year period.

       •      Toxic loadings were reduced by between 5 and 10 percent by conventional street-
              sweeping operations.

       •      Introduction of floatables to the drainage system was reduced by the installation
              and maintenance of oil/water separators, some  of which have the capability  of
              reducing oil and grease during oil spill  events to levels generally associated with
              background levels in urban storm water.

       •      Dumping of motor oil and debris in storm drains was  significantly reduced by
              increasing public awareness of storm water issues through SSWU's Stream Team
              Program and volunteer stenciling of storm drains.  A recent survey indicates that
              85 percent of area residents dispose of used  oil  at a recycling facility.

       •      Dumping of motor oil  and  household  chemicals was also reduced through
              SSWU's Oil Recycling and Hazardous  Waste Program.  SSWU collected 2,100
              gallons of petroleum products at a recycling event in October 1993.

       •      Total solids in urban runoff originating from residential yards were reduced by
              increasing public awareness of practices such as pet waste and litter control.

       •      A wide variety of local businesses work with SSWU water quality staff to prevent
              storm water pollution at the source through an innovative program called Business
                                          B-4

-------
             Partners for Clean Water.

Protection or Restoration of Ecological Resources

       •     Volunteers have planted thousands of native trees and shrubs along 10 miles of
             Bellevue's open streams to shade stream waters and enhance fish habitat.  Other
             stream enhancement projects conducted through the Stream Team Program have
             reduced streambank erosion  which also lowered water temperatures and provided
             shade to enhance fish habitat.

       •     Kelsey  Creek's salmon fishery was enhanced through installation of regional
             detention basins that help mitigate peak flows and habitat improvements from
             streambank revegetation projects. Previously, this salmon fishery was limited and
             unhealthy because of high peak flows from urban runoff that altered the stream
             channel and carried pollutants.

       •     Anadramous fish populations are enhanced because SSWU' s flood control system
             is  designed to provide maximum  flood protection  with  minimum impact on
              fisheries and fish migration. During salmon spawning season, flood control gates
             remain open until significant heavy rainfall occurs.

       •      Sensitive areas (floodplains, wetlands, and steep slopes) are protected through the
              city's  Natural Determinants  Regulations,  which  prohibit  development  of
              designated areas, including  740 acres of wetlands.

        •      The city is  restoring Phantom and Larsen  Lakes  in  partnership with  the
              Washington Department  of Ecology.  Restoration measures for Phantom Lake
              over a two-year period reduced annual internal phosphorus loading to the lake by
              approximately 75 percent and reduced annual external phosphorus loading by 39
              to 54 percent. The trophic status of Phantom Lake improved substantially after
              implementation of restoration measures, although it remains a eutrophic lake.

        •      Ecological and aesthetic features of the natural environment are preserved through
              regulation of new development under city codes and a Comprehensive Plan to
              reflect the philosophy that  development should be integrated naturally with  the
              environment and preserve rather than overcome natural features.

 Recreation Activity

        •     Kelsey Creek, a natural water channel that was developed to convey storm water
              from the city of Bellevue to Lake Washington, provides recreational opportunities
              such as canoeing, birdwatching, and hiking.

        •     Cleanup of Mercer Slough (a 325-acre wetland), along with stream and wildlife
                                           B-5

-------
              enhancement in Mercer Slough Nature Park, resulted in increased canoeing on the
              slough and increased visitation to the park's interpretive trail.

              Phantom and Larsen Lakes furnish recreational opportunities such as fishing and
              educational opportunities for school children, who visit the lakes for environmen-
              tal education projects.
Economic Activity
              Clean water in Bellevue and the surrounding Puget Sound area is important for
              drinking, food sources, recreation, and industry.
                                      References
"Bellevue Washington: A Leader in Surface Water Management." Storm and Surface Water
Utility Department, City of Bellevue, Washington.

Diessner, D. "The Bellevue Storm and Surface Water Utility: A Case History of a Successful
Urban Surface Water Management Program." prepared for Storm and Surface Water Utility
Department, City of Bellevue, Washington.

"The Metro Monitor," Municipality of Metropolitan Seattle, October  1993.

Personal communication with Wendy Skony, Program Coordinator, Bellevue Storm and Surface
Water Utility, December 8, 1993.

Personal communication with  John Frodge, Municipality of Metropolitan Seattle, December 9,
1993.

"Phantom/Larsen Lake Phase IIB Restoration Project." Final report prepared by KCM, October
1993.

"Storm Water Utilities:  Innovative Financing for Storm Water Management."   Prepared by
Apogee Research, Inc., for the Water Policy Branch, Office of Policy Analysis, Office of
Policy,  Planning and Evaluation, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency.  Draft final report,
March 1992.

EPA.  1992.  "Environmental Impacts of Storm Water Discharges: A National Profile." EPA
841-R-92-001.  Office of Water. June 1992.

EPA. 1990. "Storm Water Guidance Impact Analysis: Volume II: Case Studies." Draft.  Office
of Water.  May 15, 1990.
                                         B-6

-------
                                                                 APPENDIX C
               BENEFITS OF TOXICS REDUCTION CASE STUDDZS
A.  Toxics discharge ban or restriction

       Sources  of bioaccumulative pollutants  include direct releases to water, atmospheric
       deposition, and contaminated surface run-off.  A multi-media approach is necessary to
       reduce the amount of bioaccumulative pollutants in the environment (EPA, 1993c).

       Mercury

                    Elevated  levels in humans  may result in damage to the kidneys and
                    nervous system, and may cause developmental effects.

                    Human exposure to mercury is generally through ingestion of fish. From
                    0 1 to 0.2 percent of the U.S. population (250,000 to 500,000 people)
                    currently exceed the World Health Organization  "safe level" for daily
                    methylmercury intake (EPA, 1993b).

                    Of fish advisories in the United States, 60 percent are due to mercury
                    (issued in 27 states) (EPA, 1993a).

                    The Toxic Release Inventory (TRI) reports 19,742 pounds of mercury
                    released  to  air in 1991  and 735 pounds released to  surface waters  or
                    POTWs  in 1991 (EPA,  1993c).

                    Atmospheric deposition  of mercury accounts for almost 60 percent of the
                    mercury loadings to Lake Superior (UC, 1993).

 B. Intermediate Controls

        Over 20 years of effluent guideline development, facilities have used end-of-pipe
        treatment  to comply  with  limitations.   Setting limits  prior to end-of-pipe control
        technologies would promote  source  reduction  and prevent multi-media transfer ot
        pollutants.

        1.     Pulp. Paoer. and Paperboard (EPA, 1987b)

               EPA's recently proposed best available technology (BAT) regulations requires in-
               plant control of chlorinated organics (e.g., dioxin) potentially eliminating 19 fish
               advisories.
                                           C-l

-------
        2-     Organic Chemicals. Plastics, and Synthetic Fibers (EPA, 1987a)

               Steam stripping could remove up to  46,000 metric tons per year of volatile
               organic compounds and one annual cancer case, with resulting monetized benefits
               of steam stripping ranging from $10 to $64- million  ($1982).

        3-     Pharmaceutical Manufacturing  (Radian Corp., 1993) (under development)

               The current release of up to 61,000 metric tons per year could be eliminated by
               intermediate controls, such as steam stripping.

                                       References

 EPA.   1993a.   "A  National Fish Consumption  Advisory  Database:   A  Step Toward
 Consistency."  Office of Water/Office of Science and Technology.

 EPA.  1993b.  "Draft Report to  Congress: Deposition of Toxic Air Pollutants to the "Great
 Waters." Office of Air Quality Planning and  Standards.

 EPA.  1993c.  "1991 Toxics Release Inventory."  EPA 745-R-93-003.

 EPA.  1987a.   "Regulatory Impact Analysis of the Effluent Guidelines Regulation for the
 Organic Chemicals, Plastics, and  Synthetic Fibers Industry."
      TA',  "ReSulatory ImPact Assessment  for the Proposed Effluent Guidelines and
NESHAP for the Pulp, Paper, and Paperboard Industry.  EPA-821-R-93-020.

                                   -  " A strategy for yittual EUmination of parsisteM
Radian Corporation.  1993.  Technical memorandum to J. Keating at Versar, Inc.

Additional Material

Baker, J.,  T. Church,  S. Eisenreich, W. Fitzgerald, and  Scudlark, J., 1993.   Relative
Atmospheric Loadings of Toxic Contaminants and Nitrogen to the Great Waters.  Prepared for
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards
                                        C-2

-------
                                                                   APPENDIX D
                   DETAILED AGGREGATE BENEFIT ANALYSIS
                         Selected Urban-based Pollution Sources
 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

       This paper provides information on the anticipated economic benefits of controlling
 urban-based sources of water pollution as called for in the Initiative. We have estimated values
 for a limited number of economic categories.  Although we have identified other categories for
 which positive benefits from water quality improvements are likely, these other categories have
 not been quantified in this paper due to limited information.

       This analysis  begins with informed judgement about  the  extent  of water quality
 improvement that may result from implementing the Initiative's CSO and storm sewer provisions
 relative to current conditions.  We assume  that in all cases where CSOs or storm sewers  are
 thought to be the leading source of impaired urban waters (i.e., based upon the 305(b) reports),
 the implementation of these provisions will restore; these  waters to fishable and swimmable
 quality. Furthermore, for those waters where other sources  share significant responsibility with
 CSOs and storm sewers for precluding the  attainment of fishable and swimmable quality,  we
 assume two things:  first, 50 percent of the responsibility  lies with  CSOs and storm sewers;
 second, that implementation of other provisions of the  act in combination with the CSO and
 storm sewer provisions will result in fishable and swimmable quality in the affected waters.
 Thus, we recognize that uncertainty about the actual extent of impaired waters may lead to over-
 or underestimating the economic benefit range, but that our  method of attributing responsibility
 for impairments and our assumptions  about the  efficacy of  the  provisions may tend to
 overestimate the economic benefit range.

       Beyond the physical, chemical, and biological changes that may result from the CSO and
 storm sewer provisions, for economic evaluation it is also necessary to estimate the effects these
 changes have on humans and other economic entities (i.e., industry).  For the purposes of this
 assessment, we aggregate these sources of benefits into  four primary categories: (1) enhanced
 freshwater recreation, aesthetics, and nonuse benefits; (2) enhanced marine recreation, aesthetic,
 and nonuse benefits; (3) cost savings or increased output for withdrawal or diversionary users;
 and (4) cost savings or increased output for commercial fisheries. In the event that human health
 effects were not subsumed in the benefit estimates of one or more of the four primary categories
 we include it as a fifth category.  In addition to quantifying an economic benefit range for each
 of these categories,  we mention the other potential changes in the economic activities of
 consumers and producers that we failed to quantify.

       According  to  the  existing economic literature on  the benefits  of water quality
improvements, enhanced water-based recreation and aesthetics, and perhaps the non-use values
                                         D-l

-------
that people may hold for the preservation of the nation's aquatic ecosystems are the largest
sources of quantifiable economic benefits.  The vast number of people who recreate in a water
setting each year testifies to the importance of this resource.  More to the point, a growing
number of economic studies document the influence that water quality characteristics have on
which water bodies people choose to visit, how often they engage in water-based recreation
activities, and, how much they are willing to pay for incremental improvements in water quality.
Less  abundant  are studies  demonstrating the link between water quality improvements and
increases  in peoples' non-use values.  These values are believed to  exist, based in part upon
survey responses from people who do not currently use the nation's surface waters for recreation
or for their aesthetics but nonetheless indicate a willingness to pay for achieving certain water
quality standards.

       No primary studies attempt to estimate the enhanced recreation, aesthetics,  and non-use
benefits of water quality improvements that attributable to the CSO and storm sewer provisions
of the Initiative. However, there have been studies that attempt to ascertain the total economic
value that households place on the achievement of incremental improvements in virtually all of
the nation's lakes, rivers, and streams (i.e., marine waters were  not included) (Mitchell and
Carson,  1984,  1986; Carson and Mitchell,  1993; Lyon and Farrow, 1992).   As a part of this
research effort, a method of allocating households' willingness to pay for improvements in local
water quality was  also devised.  This method of apportioning total willingness to  pay for sub-
national  changes in water quality  is described in  more  detail in  the following section  on
freshwater benefits.

       The  remaining  quantifiable economic  benefits  (i.e.,  enhanced  marine recreation,
aesthetics, and non-use values; commercial fishing; water diversions; and human health) are
small compared with the freshwater benefits.  In addition, the economic basis for estimating
these benefits is less defensible.  We rely entirely upon secondary studies to suggest a plausible
range of benefits  for these categories.  Finally, we mention briefly other possible economic
benefits  to people and economic entities that may or may not be subsumed in the foregoing
analyses.  We believe mentioning  these potential economic effects is important because  we
cannot rule them out on  the basis of current knowledge.

Analysis  of Net Benefits for Urban Provisions of the Initiative

       Public and private capital and human resources committed to implement the  Initiative can
be used for alternative productive purposes, so the opportunity costs of these resources should
be compared with the economic benefits.  When attempting to describe the relation of benefits
to costs, it  is necessary to know the schedule of these improvements.   Discounting and
annualizing both the costs and benefits captures the opportunity costs of the resources, and
provides an analytical framework that enables one to make a more precise comparison between
costs and benefits when values for either of the two categories varies with time. The nature of
environmental  risks the Initiative is intended to reduce suggests that despite significant initial
investments in capital and human  resources,  the immediate effects on water quality will be
modest, and it will take time to fully attain many of the projected water quality improvements
                                          D-2

-------
and economic benefits.

       To illustrate how the gradual attainment of the benefits may influence the benefit-cost
comparison, the figures in Tables D-l and D-2 show the annualized monetary costs and benefits
from control of urban sources under proposed and pending spending. In Table Y., two of the
three aggregate benefit  estimates provide for the gradual attainment of benefits, applying
different discount rates to an assumed future stream  of benefits.   The selection of the two
discount rates reflects Administration guidelines on the application of discounting to costs and
benefits (seven percent), as compared to the adoption of a social rate of time preference (three
percent).  The  discounted annualized benefits are some twenty to thirty percent lower than the
annualized benefit estimate that fails to account for the expected delays in achieving tangible
water quality improvements. This serves to demonstrate the sensitivity of the results to both the
time and discounting features of the analysis.   Specifically, it illustrates that a more favorable
depiction of the benefits in relation to the cost estimates occurs when timing and discounting are
not introduced  in the analysis.

       Comparing the annualized  costs and benefits under any of the three annualized benefit
estimation scenarios, it is apparent that the range of estimated monetary costs and benefits do
not presently overlap.  Despite information of this type, the Administration feels it is important
to proceed with the Initiative for several reasons.  As stated throughout the text, and documented
in the supplemental materials, there are great uncertainties associated with both the cost and
benefit estimates that are not captured in the presentation of the numerical results.  For example,
although the national cost estimates have attempted to account for targeting of watersheds in
need of improvement and emphasized prevention measures over command-and-control strategies,
the data used for the analysis still do not fully reflect the consequences of providing flexibility
in the identification of problems and solutions. There are also a number of tangible benefits for
which monetary estimates have not been developed.  So as to better inform decisionmakers and
the public in the future, EPA is proposing a comprehensive benefit-cost study of the pollution
controls in the CWA reauthorization.  This study will reduce the uncertainties surrounding the
benefits and cost estimates.

        Despite the uncertainties,  an important contribution of the economic analysis has been
 its  ability  to  document  the significant  savings  the  Initiative is proposing  compared  to
 requirements called for in existing legislation.  Therefore, the Initiative demonstrates a genuine
 effort to achieve cost-effective regulatory management approaches to improving the nation's
 polluted  waters.    Equally important,  the public's  right  to enjoy clean  waters,  and the
 demonstration of their preferences through consistent aggressive federal legislation, have served
 as inputs into  the development of Administration policy.  Strong public support for additional
 pollution control programs persists,  as documented by national opinion polls, some of which
 report that a strong majority of respondents  agree that  the nation has not gone far enough to
 control water  pollution.

        The results of the aggregate analysis of incremental costs and benefits from controlling
 urban sources are provided in Tables D-l and D--2.  Following these tables, the paper provides
                                            D-3

-------
information used in calculating the economic value for each of the benefit categories.  We have
attempted to provide information on all of the facts and assumptions used to formulate the
economic benefit estimates.
                                        D-4

-------
                                    Table D-l

Summary of Aggregate Annualized  Costs  from Control of Urban Sources Under the
Initiative and Pending Spending (CSOs, Storm water, Toxics)
Cost Category
Municipal Costs
Phase I Storm water
Phase II Storm water
CSO Controls
CZARA Non-Point Controls
Pending Spending (Great Lakes,
Sludge)
Subtotal Municipal
^^•^^^•••^•^M ^— 1— B^""
Private Sector
Phase I Storm water
Phase II Storm water
Pollution Prevention Plans
Domestic Sewage Exclusion
Nonpoint Source Controls
Subtotal Private Sector
^^^^•— i— ^^"— ^^™
Total Quantified Costs in Urban Areas
Range: I.
(Millions
$ 1,650
$ 1,030
$2
$390
1
$ 6,610
•M^HMK^HI^HMI
$ 2,360
$345
$60
$
$233
$ 3,278
•HBHIMH^M^BH
$ 9,888
Non-Quantified Costs
                                                            $90
                                                                $ 120
                                                           $ 280
   State Administration Costs (Urban portion of $650m)
   Federal Compliance (Urban portion of $945m) - excludes abandoned mines.
   Groundwater Controls (Urban portion of $150m to $600m)
   Further Water Quality Criteria and Standards and  sediment criteria
   Toxics Bans
   Other Pending Spending (e.g., Great Lakes, Pulp  and Paper Effluent Guidelines, Air
   MACT standards)	,____=_=
 Source: Summary of Tables 19-22.
                                         D-5

-------
                                                Table D-2
 Summary of Aggregate Annualized Benefits from Control of Urban Sources Under the
 Initiative and Pending Spending (CSOs, Storm water, Toxics)
                                                                                  Range: Low - High
                                                                                  (Millions of 1993 $)
                                             Quantified Benefits
   Freshwater Recreational Fishing and Swimming (use and nonuse)
   $ 650 - $ 4,670
   Marine Recreational Fishing (use only)
    $40-  $440
   Marine Nonconsumptive Recreation (use only)
    $ 30 -  $ 300
   Marine and Freshwater Commercial Fishing
   $ 40 -  $ 190
   Withdrawal or Diversionary Uses
    $ 20 -   $ 80
   Human Health Effects (from risks associated with exposure to pollutants via
   swimming activity and seafood consumption)1
   $ 40 -  $ 320
   Sub-total: Quantified Benefits2

   Assuming immediate attainment of benefits3
           (i)      Annualized Benefits (no lag and no discounting, thus a
                   simple summation of individual categories)
   Assuming a gradual attainment of benefits over the first 15 year period that
   all Urban Source Controls are adopted.4
           (ii)      Annualized Benefits (seven percent discount rate, gradual
                   attainment over first 15 years)
           (iii)     Annualized benefits (three percent  discount rate, gradual
  	            attainment over first 15 years)
 (i) $ 820 - $ 6,000




(ii) $560-$4,100

(iii) $ 660 - $ 4,900
                                          Non-Quantified Benefits
  - Marine Recreational Swimming (nonhealth effects)
  - Other Human Health Effects in Marine and Freshwaters (see Note 1)
  - Recreational Hunting- Freshwater Nonconsumptive Recreation (see Note 1)
  - Marine Recreational Boating
  - Other Non-use Benefits (Marine Waters - see Note 1)
  - Other avoided costs (e.g., water storage, dredging, damages from floods)
  - Restoration of biodiversity and ecosystem integrity
  Given information and methods used to calculate the quantified benefits, some portion of the benefits associated with thesi
categories may be captured in the monetary range ascribed to freshwater recreation fishing and swimming.
1 Assumes no double counting of benefits or substitution effects between different categories when developing aggregate national
estimates. Also assumes that all lower and upper ends of the range for each quantified category describe the aggregate lower
and upper bound estimate.  Absent information on the distribution or probability of attaining benefits defined by the estimated
range, we can not calculate a "most likely"  estimate.
3 Assuming no lag between implementation of controls, recovery of natural ecological systems, and economic behavior that forms
the basis  for the economic benefit measures.
4 These estimates of the economic benefits are more appropriate to use when comparing quantified costs and benefits, given the
anticipated lag time between introduction of the control measures and full realization of the environmental and economic benefits.
The calculated annualized figure is based on assuming a gradual attainment of benefits up through year fifteen, and a constant
future benefits stream after the fifteenth year has been reached.
                                                   D-6

-------
FRESHWATER-SPECIFIC CATEGORIES

Freshwater Recreational Fishing and Swimming

1.  Baseline Water Resource Quality for Urban Households

Facts

  •    24%  of water bodies  in urban areas are fully supporting their designated uses, while
       nationwide 50% of water bodies are fully meeting designated uses.

  •    At the national level, 32% of all water bodies are partially or not supporting aquatic life
       use, and 24% of all water bodies are partially or not supporting fish consumption use.
       21%  of all water bodies are not or are partially supporting swimming.

  •    For modeled urban population (generally, urban areas), Kealy et al. (1993) estimate that
       48  percent  households are  located by waters not  fully fishable, and 69 percent  of
       households are located by waters not fully swimmable.

Assumptions

  •    All water bodies are beatable (conservative assumption, given modeling and water quality
       reporting data).

  •    The Kealy  et al. estimates for populations adjacent to fishable and  swimmable are
       reasonable, given that information from state  reported data on water quality conditions
       in urban areas tends to be significantly poorer than the reported nationwide statistics.

Finding Used for Analysis

  •    48 percent of the national urban population lives by water bodies that do not fully support
       fishable uses.

  •   69 percent of the national urban population lives by water bodies that do not fully support
       swimming uses.

Information on Urban Population1

Total population: 247 million persons
    1 Information from the storm water section of the Initiative indicates that 158 million persons are served by
 storm water systems.  The combined sewer overflow section of the Initiative identifies approximately 43 million
 persons who are served by combined sewer overflow systems. The union of these two samples  is thought to
 encompass the vast majority of households listed as urbsm by the Census bureau.  Therefore,  for purposes of
 analysis in this paper, the universe of urban households is used when calculating the percentages of households
 proximate to urban waters failing to meet fishing or swimming uses.
                                            D-7

-------
Urban population: 185.7 million persons (75%)
Population served by storm water:  158 million persons (64%)
Rural population: 61.4 million persons (25%)
Total households: 93.9 million households (2.63 per household)
Urban households: 70.6 million (2.63 per household)
Urban/Storm water households: 60.1 million (2.63 per household)
Non-Urban/Storm water households: 10.5 million (2.63 per household)
Rural households: 23.2 million (2.63 per household)

  •   Using the urban/storm water population figures as a baseline population,  29 million
      households (48% of 60.1 million households nationwide) could benefit from improved
      fishable use support, and 41 million (69% times 60.1 million households)  households
      could benefit from improved swimming use  support.

2.  Water Quality Improvements From the Initiative's CSO, Storm Water, and Toxics
Provisions
Facts
       According to the 1992 305(b) report, urban runoff and storm water are a leading source
       of impairment in 24,100 assessed river miles (30% of non-agricultural impaired and
       assessed miles, or 10% of all impaired and assessed miles, or 3% of all assessed miles,
       or 0.7% of all river miles in the nation).  Similarly, for lakes, reservoirs and ponds,
       urban runoff and storm water are a leading source of impairment in 1.31 million acres
       (52% of non-agricultural impaired and assessed acres, or 24.1% of impaired and assessed
       acres, or 7.1% of all assessed acreage, or 4.8%  of all lake acreage in the nation).
Assumptions
       Control of urban  runoff and storm  sewers,  where  they  are a leading source of
       impairment, will restore fishable/swimmable conditions. Existing municipal wastewater
       pollution concerns, where they are limiting water quality in these urban waters, will be
       controlled under existing CWA authority.

       The Initiative's CSO, storm water and toxics provisions will restore fishable/swimmable
       conditions in 39% of those urban water bodies where urban runoff and storm sewers are
       the leading  source of impairment.  Excluding agriculturally impaired rivers and lakes,
       urban runoff and storm sewers are the leading sources  of impairment in approximately
       39% of the remaining water bodies. This figure is based on averaging the percentages
       provided for river  miles  and  lakes acreage where urban runoff and storm water is a
       leading source of impairment.  Assume that the other 61 % of the impaired waters located
       next to  these urban households will improve, in part, from these provisions.   The
       contribution of these sources  relative to the problem is assumed to be 50%.  To the
       extent that other sources of pollution or other natural limitations not considered in these
       figures would preclude these  waters from fully supporting  fishing and  swimming, the
       quantified benefits from the Initiative's provisions will not be realized.  This number is
                                         D-8

-------
       not founded on  empirical research on relative loadings of jpollutants from different
       sources occurring in these affected waters but is based on the informed judgement of
       EPA staff.2

Findings Used for Analysis

  •    The Initiative's CSO, storm water and toxics provisions will be necessary and sufficient
       for restoring swimmable/fishable conditions in approximately 39% of the impaired water
       bodies proximate to urban populations.

•     For the remaining 61 % of impaired water bodies near urban populations, the Initiative's
       urban provisions will be necessary but insufficient to ensure improvements occur. The
       relative proportion of the impairment that can be attributed to these sources is assumed
       to  be 50%.  This figure will be used to attribute the anticipated economic benefits of
       improvements to the Initiative's policies that control urban nonpoint pollution sources.

  •    Therefore, 11.3 million urban households are expected to achieve fishable conditions, and
       16 million urban households are expected to achieve swimmable conditions  solely due
       to  the Initiative's CSO, storm water, and toxics provisions. Thus,  we apportion 100%
       of the estimated economic benefits of these improvements to the Initiative's provisions.
       The remaining 17.7 million urban households will see improvements  in fishing from
       control of these and other pollution problems. Likewise, the remaining 25 million urban
       households will achieve improvements in their swimming conditions as a result of these
       provisions and other pollution control requirements. For  these last two segments of the
       urban population, the benefits  from these  water quality changes will be  partially
       apportioned (50% of the total benefits) to urban nonpoint control policies.

3.  Economic Benefits from Initiative's CSO, Storm Water and Toxics Provisions

Facts

  •    Mitchell and Carson estimate the following willingness to pay for certain use and non-use
       recreational opportunities from water resource quality improvements:

       Valuation:

        > Boatable to fishable $104 ($70*1.33 inflation factor*!.11 real income growth above
       adjustments)

        > Fishable to swimmable $115 ($78 above adjustments)
    2 Statistics on urban nonpoint loadings relative to total point and non-rural nonpoint loadings suggest that urban
 nonpoint loadings constitute a significant fraction of total pollution loadings.  Using information on point source
 loadings and average wet weather conditions for the early 1990s, 39% of total suspended solid loadings originated
 from point sources and 61 % from urban nonpoint sources.

                                           D-9

-------
 Assumptions

   •    The Mitchell and Carson study is representative of actual willingness to pay.

   •    When calculating fishing benefits, assume that affected waters are already at beatable
        status.  Likewise when calculating swimming benefits, assume that all affected waters
        have reached fishable status, either as a baseline condition or as a consequence of these
        policies. In doing this, we can aggregate the estimated benefits of improving fishing and
        swimming without fear of double-counting the economic benefits of achieving fishable
        or swimmable water quality conditions.

   •    We draw upon information from Carson and Mitchell on  their  surveyed households'
        allocation of economic benefits from the attainment of water quality conditions in the
        nation's freshwaters.   As an upper  bound estimate, we assume that for those urban
        households located in places having impaired water  quality, that two-thirds of their
        national stated WTP for a particular level of use  support (i.e., fishable or swimmable
        water quality) is directed at water quality improvements in their immediate area.  As a
        lower bound estimate, we assume that these households are willing to allocate 12% of
        their total national stated WTP for local water quality improvements.  Note that when
        a greater proportion of their WTP is  directed at local waters, it follows that these same
        persons wiU not be willing-to-pay much for  achieving the same fishing and swimming
        uses in remaining waters located beyond their immediate area.

  •    Where it is both necessary and sufficient to  undertake the Initiative's urban provisions
        to attain improvement in fishing and swimming conditions, 100%  of the benefits are
        attributed to these provisions.  For those waters where it is necessary but  not sufficient
        to undertake the Initiative's urban provisions to attain fishing and  swimming uses, 50%
        of the benefits to households located near these waters are attributed to these provisions.
       In other words, the assignment of benefits to provisions in the Initiative is  organized by
        source (e.g., CSOs, storm  water), which is  consistent with the information  on the
       assignment or attribution of causes of impairment to sources identified in the Initiative.

  •    We use the Carson and Mitchell research to estimate the benefits to urban households not
       located  by impaired urban  waters and to all rural households  of  the water  quality
       improvements that can be achieved as a result of the Initiative's urban provisions. As
       an upper bound, we assume that these households are  willing to allocate  12% of their
       total national stated WTP for these water quality improvements. As a lower bound, we
       assume that they would be unwilling to allocate any part of their national WTP for these
       improvements.  This is based, in part,  upon  Carson and Mitchell research on the non-
       urban survey respondents' stated WTP for improvements in all areas, as  compared to
       improvements in all but the nation's urban areas.  The incremental benefits to these
       persons for achieving fishable quality in urban areas could be zero, given the availability
       of substitutes and the relative  fraction of the  nation's waters that the affected  urban
       waters constitute.

The results of these assumptions  and analysis are  summarized in Table  D-3.    Additional
                                         D-10

-------
information and issues to consider in using the freshwater recreatiomil results.

Reason To Think Values Could Be Underestimated

  •    The Mitchell and Carson survey was conducted in 1983.  If the survey was repeated,
       values  might be higher today  due to greater awareness  of  water  quality conditions
       (publications), stronger preferences for water quality improvements (consumer survey
       results), and improved economic conditions.

Reasons To Think Values Could Be Overestimated

  e    Mitchell and Carson found that a sub-sample of  respondents; were almost as satisfied
       (based on WTP  estimates)  with partial improvements in waters as they were with
       achieving a 99% improvement. For example, non-urban respondents were WTP $74 to
       make waters 95% fishable and $80 to make waters 99% fishable.  We assume that WTP
       is linearly related to overall national water quality. If the relationship is non-linear, then
       marginal values of improvements as one approaches virtually nationwide use attainment
       for a particular use could be overstated.

  •    Both professional and trade literature on contingent valuation issues and Federal agency
       deliberations on  the use of contingent valuation research for developing economic
       measures  of proposed  regulatory and damage award purposes cite  serious concerns
       regarding the reliability of economic values based upon responses to survey questions.
       The majority of critical reviews of contingent valuation research suggest that these survey
       responses are larger than monitored cash payments made to obtain the desired outcome
        (Arrow, etal., 1993; Cambridge Economics, 1992; and Cummings and Harrison, 1991).
       For this and other reasons, some persons within the economic and policy analysis
        community are reluctant to make use of contingent valuation research that has not been
        conducted using a number of recommended operating standards that are designed to
        provide for more reliable empirical estimates. The Mitchell and Carson study referenced
        here  does not conform  to  the full set  of these recommendations, and thus may be
        considered too unreliable for use as a reference for this analysis.

 Additional Uncertainty

   «    Mitchell and Carson's survey instrument elicited total willingness-to-pay estimates for
        nationwide  changes in water quality conditions.  The need to disaggregate the national
        estimates to local waters and to assign some portion of these  estimates to localized
        changes is severely constrained by the information contained in the survey.  As a result,
        the attempt to distribute the values to local waters goes beyond information contained in
        the author's report. If the assumptions made here are incorrect, they can substantially
        affect the household and national estimates of the benefits of improving
                                          D-ll

-------
                                               Table D-3
Estimated National Swimming and Fishing Benefits to Controlling Urban Sources, National (1992 dollars)
  Households Benefitting From Water
  Quality Improvements Attributable to
  the Initiative's Urban Provisions
Lower Bound National Benefit
Estimate:  For affected urban
households, use 12% of national
WTP; for non-affected house-
holds, use 0%  of national WTP.
Upper Bound National Benefit
Estimate: For affected urban
households, use 67% of national
WTP; for non-affected households,
use 12% of national WTP.
 Affected urban population where
 urban sources are sufficient (assign
 100% of benefits) to relieve cause of
 impairments: 39% of impaired urban
 waters
 Affected urban population where
 urban sources are necessary but not
 sufficient (assign 50% of benefits) to
 relieve cause of impairments: 61% of
 impaired urban waters
 Other population (rural and unaffect-
 ed urban households) WTP to see
 attainment of fishing and swimming
 uses in impaired in-state urban waters
 Total WTP Estimate
 Fishing: 11.3 million households
   @ $12.5/household = $141
            million

Swimming: 16 million households
   @ $13.8/household - $221
            million
                                          TOTAL = $365 million
 Fishing: 11.3 million households
@ $69.7/household = $788 million

 Swimming: 16 million households
   @ $77. I/household = $1,234
             million
                                     TOTAL = $2,022 million
 Fishing: 17.7 million households
@ $12.5/household * (50 percent)
        = $111 million

Swimming: 25 million households
@ $13.8/household * (50 percent)
        = $173 million

    TOTAL =  $284 million
 Fishing: 17.7 million households
@ $69.7/household * (50 percent)
         = $617 million

Swimming: 25 million households
@ $77. I/household * (50 percent)
         = $964 million

   TOTAL = $1,581 million
                                         Fishing and swimming: $0
                                  Fishing: 41.6 million (urban) +
                                 23.2 million (rural) households @
                                 $12.5/household * (100%*39% +
                                    50% *61%) = $563 million

                                 Swimming: 29.6 million (urban) +
                                 23.2 million (rural) households @
                                 $13.8/household * (100%*39% +
                                    50%*61%) = $506 million

                                    TOTAL  = $1,069 million
  Lower Bound: $649 million
                                                                        Upper Bound: $4,672 million
                                                 D-12

-------
the identified sample of urban waters. For example, survey responses tried to distinguish in-
state and out-of state values.  Whether these values are distributed equally among all waters or
would  be focused on specific waters (e.g., those having known unique habitat or having
significant economic value) is not contained in the survey results.

  •    Mitchell and Carson  focus only  on freshwaters.   The survey expressly asks that
       respondents do not consider marine waters in their answers.  Nevertheless, it is possible
       that respondents may have included some marine waters hi describing their WTP.  No
       test was conducted to elicit whether respondents truly considered this in their responses.

  «    The survey attempted clarify that drinkable water quality was distinctly different from
       swimmable water quality.  However, it is unclear to what extent responses could be
       associated with improvements beyond swimmable. For example, some aquatic uses may
       still be impaired, even though the waters are swimmable.

  •    Limited research suggests that individual fishermen may be willing to pay to move
       fishable waters to levels that provide for the consumption of fish.  If correct values could
       possibly be adjusted upward to account for this additional value if not incorporated into
       the responses.

  •    The analysis relies  on information and assumptions that are used to attribute changes in
       water quality conditions (and  economic benefits) to anticipated changes in loadings of
       pollutants from urban sources. If these assumptions are incorrect, then the attribution
       of benefits to these  programs when following this methodology will result in an incorrect
       estimate of the quantified benefits from these provisions.

MARINE WATER-SPECIFIC CATEGORIES

1.  Baseline Marine Water Resource Quality

  •    24% of water bodies in urban areas are fully supporting their designated uses,  which
       compares  with 56%  of estuaries nationwide that are fully  supporting their designated
       uses. 80% of coastal waters are fully meeting their designated uses.

  e    At the national level, 22% of estuaries are partially or not supporting aquatic life use
       support, 5% are partially or not supporting fish consumption, 3(3% are partially or not
       supporting shellfishing, and 17% are partially or not supporting swimming.

2.  Marine Water Quality Improvement from Initiative's CSO, Storm Water, and Toxics
Provisions

  •    At the national level, urban runoff and storm sewers are the leading source of impairment
       in 43% of the estuaries and 58% of coastal areas.
                                         D-13

-------
Finding Used for Analysis

  •    Given that 44% of estuaries are not fully meeting their designated uses (20% for coastal
       areas) and that  urban runoff and  storm sewers are a leading cause in 43% of the
       estuaries, it is reasonable to conclude that recreational and commercial activity levels
       from the Initiative's CSO, storm water, and toxics provisions will increase from a low
       of 10% to a high of 20% over existing activity levels.

  •    Given that 75 % of population lives in urban areas and that storm sewers and urban runoff
       is a leading cause in 43% of estuaries, it is reasonable to conclude that 40% to 60% of
       the increased activity will accrue to urban users.

Marine Recreational Fishing

Following Freeman (1993), use information on the current number of saltwater fishingpersons
and shellfishing persons.  Assign a range of benefits per trip under existing water conditions.
Provide a for range of water quality improvements and effects on benefits.

Facts

Baseline number of trips per year:  92,000,000 (FWS, 1993)

Assumptions

Estimated economic values:
Lower bound: Average surplus value per trip = $10 (FWS, 1988)
Upper bound: Average surplus value per trip  = $40 (FWS, 1988)

Potential gain from water quality improvements:
Lower bound: 10% proportionate gain from baseline
Upper bound: 20% proportionate gain from baseline

Contributions from urban sources:
Lower bound: 40% contribution to nonattainment
Upper bound: 60% contribution to nonattainment

Estimated  Economic Benefits  From  the  Initiative's CSO, Storm Water, and Toxics
Provisions

Lower bound total benefit: 92,000,000 trips per year * $10/trip * 10% gain
Upper bound total benefit: 92,000,000 trips per year * $40/trip * 20% gain

Range of benefits: $ 92 million - $736 million

Benefits attributable to control of urban sources:
Lower bound: $92 million * 40% contribution = $37 million
                                        D-14

-------
Upper bound: $736 million * 60% contribution = $442 million

Nonconsumptive Recreation: Marine

Facts

Baseline number of persons engaged in oceanside wildlife viewing per year:  6,900,000 (FWS,
1993)
Baseline  number  of  persons engaged  in  wetland, marsh, and  swamp activities  per  year:
11,700,000 (FWS, 1993)

Assumptions

Because  the FWS survey did not distinguish  between  marine and freshwater wetlands and
marshes, we assume 50% of the baseline total is on marine waters: 50% of 11,700,000 per year
 = 5,850,000 persons/year.

Estimated participation rates for both types of activities:
Lower bound on number of activity days for each, purpose: 5 days/person/year
Upper bound on number of activity days for each purpose: 10 days/person/year

Therefore, the number of days of activity are:
Lower bound:  12,750,000 persons per year * 5 days/year = 63.8 million total days
Upper bound:  12,750,000 persons per year *  10 days/year = 127.5 million total days

 Potential gain from water quality improvements:
 Lower bound: 10% proportionate gain from baseline
 Upper bound: 20% proportionate gain  from baseline

 Contributions from urban sources:
 Lower bound: 40% contribution to nonattainmenl:
 Upper bound: 60% contribution to nonattainment

 Estimated  Economic Benefits  from the Initiative's CSO,  Stoinn Water, and Toxics
 Provisions

 Estimated economic  values assumed to be the same for both types of activities:
 Lower bound:  63.8m days * $10/day * 10% gain
 Upper bound:  127.5m days * $20/day * 20% gain

 Range of benefits = $64 million - $510 million

 Benefits attributable to control of urban sources:
 Lower bound: $64 million * 40% contribution == $26 million
 Upper bound:  $510  million * 60% contribution = $306 million
                                         D-15

-------
 OTHER CATEGORIES - NOT SPECIFIC TO MARINE AND FRESHWATERS

 Marine and Freshwater Commercial Fishing

 Facts

 The national ex-vessel (wholesale) value  is  $3.6 billion (EPA, Clean Water and American
 Economy, 1992).
 Near coastal fishery represents approximately 50% of the total ex-vessel value. Figures are
 dominated by marine commercial fishery.

 Assumptions

 Estimated consumer and producer surpluses (low: 50%, high: 90%) of ex-vessel value (RIA for
 GLWQI, EPA, 1993)

 Baseline surplus values for current near-coastal marine fisheries and water quality conditions:
 Lower bound: $3.6 billion * 50% near-coastal * 50% surplus = $900 million
 Upper bound: $3.6 billion * 50%  near-coastal * 90% surplus = $1,620 million

 Potential gain from water quality improvements:
 Lower bound: 10% proportionate  gain from baseline
 Upper bound: 20% proportionate gain from baseline

 Contributions from urban sources:
 Lower bound: 40% contribution to nonattainment
 Upper bound: 60% contribution to nonattainment

 Estimated Economic Benefits from the Initiative's  CSO,  Storm  Water,  and  Toxics
 Provisions

 Estimated  economic values:
 Lower bound: $900 million * 10% gain
 Upper bound: $1,620 million * 20% gain

 Range of benefits = $90 million - $324 million

 Benefits attributable to control of urban sources:
Lower bound: $90 million * 40% contribution = $36 million
Upper bound: $324 million * 60% contribution =  $194 million

Withdrawal or Diversionary Uses
                           *
SOURCES: Freeman, 1982, and Kealy, 1993 (citing Morris and Cushman 1993 report to EPA).

Very little  information is available  on the actual effects of water quality conditions on the costs
                                       D-16

-------
of treating intake water. Therefore, the Morris and Cushman paper first estimated or reported
the costs of treating water, given recent rates of consumption for a variety of economic sectors.
They include a number of sectors (see below).  In most sectors,  tolal treatment costs  were
estimated using recent  figures on quantities consumed and unit cost estimates.  For irrigated
agriculture, changes in net revenues from elimination of anthropogenic sources of salinity formed
the basis for the estimate.  Using these figures, one could attempt to define what proportion of
costs have reduced as  a result of improvements to current water quality and what further
improvements from additional steps to reduce water pollutants could be realized.

The  sectors and their treatment costs are as follows:

Facts

Manufacturing: $550 million (1990$)
Thermoelectric: $370 million (1990$)
Drinking water treatment: $1,500 million (1990$)
Materials  damage to household  items:  $2,100 miHion (1990$)
Household health through drinking water exposure: $3,000 million (1990$)
Irrigated agriculture: $430 million (1990$)

These total approximately $8 billion in treatment costs that could be influenced by intake water
quality.  Of this amount, the savings  that could be attributed to less polluted water quality is
highly uncertain.  Kealy (1994)  attempt to describe the reduced costs from existing CWA-based
improvements (see attachment), although their paper, and the original Morris and Cushman
paper, are highly critical of the data and assumptions used to construct these estimates.

Assumptions

To date, as a result of  CWA activities, water quality improvements have reduced these costs as
follows:

Manufacturing: $110 million
Drinking water treatment: $ 200 million
Uncertain for remaining sectors,  assumed to be zero

 If we assume that further water quality improvements could have the effect of reducing the
 remaining costs by 1% (low) to 5% (high) and that the CWA amendments would be distributed
 to urban areas using 40% (from marine and freshwater attribution figures), then the additional
 benefits range for the  following categories are as follows:

 Estimated Economic Benefits  From the  Initiative's CSO, Storm Water,  and Toxics
 Provisions

 Illustrate with manufacturing sector

 $550 million (original cost) - $110 million (cost .savings to date) = $440 million
                                          D-17

-------
 Lower bound cost saving of further water quality improvements: $440 million * 1%
 Upper bound cost saving of further water quality improvements: $440 million * 5%

 Range of potential cost savings: $4 million - $20 million

 Savings attributable to control of urban sources:
 Lower bound: $4m * 40%  = $1.6 million
 Upper bound: $20m * 40% = $8.8 million

 Summary of affected categories:
 Manufacturing: urban sources $2 million - $9 million
 Drinldng water treatment: urban sources $5 million - $25 million
 Materials damage: urban sources $8 million - $40 million
 Thermoelectric: urban sources $2 million - $7 million
 Human health: not estimated.
 Irrigation agriculture: not estimated

 Totals: urban sources $17 million - $81 million

 Human Health Benefits

 Background Regarding Public Health Efifects

 Recreational benefits associated with enhanced water quality extend well beyond the increased
 level of economic activity that can be enjoyed at the state and local level.  In some instances,
 economic benefits are secondary  to  (and derived from) the public health implications of
 recreational water activities. Public health effects can result from activities such as swimming
 and fishing through the following routes of exposure:

   •   Swimming — ingestion of and/or dermal exposure to chemical contaminants or pathogens.

   •   Fishing — consumption of contaminated fish by recreational anglers and those fishing for
       subsistence.

The Agency believes that  the probability of adverse health effects (identified below) may
correlate with socioeconomic status,  race, and  age.  This  is  due  to  the susceptibility and
practices associated  with specific  age and ethnic  groups.   This paper summarizes readily
available information regarding the risks  associated  with certain recreational activities3 and
provides some information regarding particular populations at risk.

Swimming

   •   A number of studies document the risks of acute gastroenteritis resulting from bathing
       in contaminated water (NRC, 1993). In fact, swimming in even "marginally" polluted
   3 Note that boating, water skiing, or hiking (while relevant) have not been included in the analysis.

                                         D-18

-------
marine bathing water results in a significant route of exposure.

One study found that the risks of incurring  gastrointestinal illnesses are three times
greater for children less that 2 years old who are entirely submerged in the course of
swimming in contaminated water, compared with the risks to adults exposed to the same
water quality  conditions  (NRC,  1993).   This suggests that differential dose-response
functions may exist for adults and children, or that the hazards of exposure to these types
of pathogens is dependent on the physiology  of the exposed individual.  Note that the
empirical estimates below do not attempt to introduce sub-population risk calculations
into the analysis,  but rely on the dose-response relationships developed for the full
distribution of the exposed population.

The methodology for estimating risks comprises the following steps:
       Determine the level of contamination.
       Identify the interaction of the pathogen with the host (dose/response).
  -   Determine the population at risk (considering  age,  sex,  and the presence  of
       underlying conditions that make  one more susceptible).

Each swimming event results in exposure to  approximately 100 ml of water, assuming
that one's head is submerged.  The current  allowable level  of pathogen indicators in
bathing water is 35/100 ml  for saltwater and 33/100 ml for freshwater.  This results in
a predicted rate of 19 cases and 8 cases,  respectively, of gastroenteritis per 1,000 people
exposed (NRC, 1993 and EPA,  1992).

 Larger cities tend to have higher concentrations of pathogens in surrounding waters (i.e.,
 water bodies effected by wastewater discharges).

 People of color and hispanics are less likely to engage in overnight travel and, therefore,
 are subject to greater exposure near urban centers (NRDC, 1993).

 There have been 7,700 beach closures or advisories since 1988, 2,600 of which took
 place in 1992.  Significant inconsistencies  exist  in water quality monitoring and  the
 criteria for closing beaches at the state  level (NRDC, 1993).

 Approximately 40 million people swim outdoors in natural bodies of water (i.e., not in
 pools).  Nineteen percent swim 1 to 2 days per year, 42 percent 3 to 10 days per year,
 20 percent 11 to 25 days per year, and 19 percent more than 25 days per year (NPS,
  1986).

 Using the above data, there are  an estimated 455 million person-swim-days per year
  during which one is exposed to a rate of illness ranging from 8 to 19 per 1,000, or 3.6
  million to 8.6 million potential cases of gastroenteritis per year.

  A case of giardiasis costs about $50 to $100 per day (Harrington, .1986, 1993).

  Assuming one day of gastrointestinal illness (low-end estimate), costs  are estimated to
                                     D-19

-------
        be between $180 and $860 million per year.  The extent to which these costs can be
        avoided is unknown.

    •   Other diseases include ear infections, eye irritation, skin rashes, and sore throats.

 Fishing

    •   A recent EPA study of 388 fishing sites (many of which were targeted on the basis of
        their being suspected of having high concentrations of pollutants due to their locations)
        found 66 pollutants.  EPA performed a closer analysis of pollutants and sites for which
        adequate data were available-resulting  in 110 sites analyzed (EPA, 1993).   PCB,
        biphenyl, mercury and DDE were detected at almost  every site.

   •   Lifetime cancer risks exceeded Ifr4 at 42 sites for PCB contamination of fish alone (38
        percent of sites analyzed),  for an average fish consumption rate of 6.5  grams/day.
        Again, these sites are "hot spots" and do not represent the average toxicity at fishing sites
        across the country.

   •   Recreational anglers consume on average 30 grams per day, while subsistence fisherman
        consume 50 to 100 grams per  day.  Average consumption remains 6.5 grams per day.

   •   In 1990, 36.9 million fishing licenses were sold (Department of Commerce,  1992).
       Assuming 38 percent of these fisherman are exposed to risks of 104, 1,402 excess cancer
       cases occur over a 70 year period,  or about 20 cases per year.  Valuing each cancer case
       at $2 to $10 million, results in costs of $40 to $200 million per year.  The extent to
       which  these costs can be avoided is unknown.

   •   Results of the Wisconsin Tribes  Comparative Risk Project indicated excess lifetime
       cancer risks of 4xlQ-3.   This study assumed  half  the  consumption rate for  these
       subsistence fisherman than the  recent Columbia River study.

   •   Between  1984  and 1986, 38 states reported fish consumption advisories, sport fishing
       restrictions, or sport fishing closures.  Specifically, these measures included 3 closures,
       7 restrictions,  and 427 advisories (Sports Fishing Institute).

   •   In addition, 10 states in three  regions reported  shellfishing restrictions attributable to
       CSOs alone. This affected nearly 600,000 acres of shellfish area (Industrial Economics
       Inc.).

Summary

   •   Total estimated costs resulting from exposure to fish and water contaminants and related
       to recreational  activities is $220 million to $1.06 billion per year.

   •   We have assumed that 50 percent of these costs can be avoided due to implementation
       of the proposed amendments, and that 40 to 60 percent  of this amount is related to urban
                                        D-20

-------
      sources.  Accounting for these factors results in cost avoidance estimates of approximate-
      ly $44 to $320 million per year.

Totals: urban sources $44 million - $320 million
OTHER NONOTTANTIFIE™
                                     CATEGORIES
Marine Recreation Swimming:  Relationship between user days  and water quality,  access,
substitutes, and the effectiveness of control programs is uncertain  (e.g., average consumer
surplus per swimming day « $25/day; Walsh et al., 1988).  Alternative source of information
found that annual benefits per beach user for a 20% decrease in pollution for Chesapeake Bay
beaches showed that users of heavily attended beaches would be WTP $50 to $70 per year,
while 20% reductions at less desirable beaches would be valued at $1-$20 per year per person
(Bockstaeletal., 1987).

Hnman Health Effects:  Uncertain about how many and what type of health effects would be
avoided from improvements in national water quality conditions. Might expect reduced numbers
of gastrointestinal disease from exposures to contaminated water and foods. Reduced morbidity
and mortality risks associated  with toxic pollutants in drinking water and foods, particularly
those  foods  that bioaccumulate toxics.  Unclear how many subsistence  fishermen follow
consumption advisories.

p^r^tinnal Hunting: Some forms of hunting are affected by water quality conditions due to
 the influence of water quality on habitat (availability of living space,  food sources, and impacts
 on reproduction). It is unclear how many additional trip days and their value for specific water
 quality programs are included in  the  Carson and Mitchell survey.   For  example, average
 consumer surplus per migratory bird hunting day is about $ 40 per day (Walsh et al  1988 ; of
 the total number of migratory hunting days 22 million, 9 million are for ducks, and 7 million
 are for geese (FWS,  1993).

 T^hwatei-hased Mnnnnnsumtrtive Uses: It is unclear whether the Mitchell and Carson survey
 captured all freshwater-based  nonconsumptive recreation benefits.   It may be  of particular
 importance that attainment of swimmable quality still leaves room  for improvement to water
 quality that will support other aquatic life. However, the survey may not capture these effects
 in the base case. The number of persons engaged in nonconsumptive activities is substantial.
 For example, 19.2 million persons were engaged in nonconsumptive  activity by lakes and rivers
 (FWS, 1993), and the average consumer surplus per day for nonconsumptive wildlife activities
 is « $25/day (Walsh et al., 1988).

 Marine. Recreational Boating:  It is unclear how responsive boaters are to changes in water
 quality alone.  Some portion of this has presumably been captured  in the estimates of benefits
  for marine recreational fishing. In a study of Chesapeake Bay boaters individuals responded
  that, depending upon their destination site, they would be WTP $1  to  $20 per year for a 20%
  reduction in water pollutants in the Bay (Bockstael et al., 1987).

  Nnnmer Benefits for Marine W*«™- Quality Improvements:  Freshwater benefit estimates likely
                                          D-21

-------
 included use and nonuse benefits.  The above marine recreational benefits only attempted to
 include potential welfare changes associated with active participants.

 Potential Avoided Costs: Better functioning natural systems may be able to provide a number
 of services  that are currently provided  by  manmade systems (e.g.,  flood  control  water
 purification, sediment disposal).                                                  '

 (a)  Water Storage

 The amount of water storage capacity and the capacity lost annually due to sedimentation in the
 48 states has been estimated for reservoirs with 5,000 acre-feet or more of total capacity af
 Total storage capacity: 728.3 million acre-feet
 Usable storage capacity: 472.1 million acre-feet
 Water storage capacity lost: 1.64 million acre-feet (average 0.22%)
 Reservoir sedimentation from cropland: 0.39 million acre-feet.

 SOURCE: Crowder, 1987

 (b) Dredging Operations

 Federal and non-federal dredging in coastal areas disposal methods and costs:
 Upland - 27 million cubic yards ;  $127 million (1991$)
 Open ocean - 92 million cu yds.; $143 million (1991$)
Beach nourishment - 8 million cu yds;  $33 million (1991$)
Aquatic confined - 52 million cu.yds; $518 million (1991$)
Mixed - 36 million cu yds.;  $130 million (1991$)
Total - 216 million cu yds.; $ 950 million (1991$)
SOURCE: EPA, 1993c
                                        D-22

-------
ADDITIONAL ECONOMIC INFORMATION

EMPLOYMENT (Administration Infrastructure Stimulus Package, 1993)

•     Each $1.0 billion in environmental investment creates about 33,000 jobs.

             13,000 direct jobs
             20,000 indirect jobs

COMMERCIAL MARINE ECONOMIC ACTIVITY
(EPA, Clean Water and American Economy paper, 1993a)

•     Contributes about $16.5 billion to GNP
•      1988 employment: about 363,703

RECREATION ECONOMIC ACTIVITY
(EPA, Clean Water and American Economy paper, 1993a; and FWS,, 1993))

•      FISHING
       31 million freshwater anglers and 8.9 million saltwater anglers (1991)
       440 million freshwater fishing days and 75 million saltwater fishing days
       Total spending for fishing: $24 billion (1991$)

•     HUNTING
       14.1 million hunters
       22 million migratory bird related hunting days
       Total spending for waterfowl hunting: $0.7 billion (1991$)

 •     SWIMMING
       14.8 million swimming days in lakes or streams (1985)
       8.4 million in marshes and wetlands
       5.7 million in oceans

 •     NONCONSUMPTIVE USES
       76.1 million participants (1991)
       54.7 million observe wildlife
       19.1 million observe waterfowl and shorebirds
       Total spending: $18.1 billion  (1991$)

 •     BOATING
       Total spending: $20 billion in 1988.
       Supports 6,200 manufacturers of boats, motors, and trailers
       Supports 8,300 marinas, boat yards, and yacht clubs
       Employs 600,000 people
                                        D-23

-------
POLLUTION CONTROL INDUSTRY

•     EMPLOYMENT (EPA, 1993a)
      120,000 design, engineering, and consulting.
      88,000 water treatment equipment
      25,000 analytical services
      13,000 instruments
      12,325 chemical suppliers
      198,000 construction
      Total: 456,000 direct

•     NATIONAL EXPENDITURES (EPA, Cost of Clean, 1990)
      $50 billion In 1992 for CWA related (annualized, 7%, 1992$)
      $5 billion in 1992 for drinking water (annualized, 7%, 1992$)

•     EXPORTS (EPA, International Trade study, 1993b)
      $450 million (1991)

•     IMPORTS
      $216 million (1991)
                                    D-24

-------
Appended Material on Chesapeake Bay

Various illustrations of economic benefit studies for changes in Chesapeake Bay water quality.
SOURCE: Benefits From Improvement in Chesapeake Bay Water Quality (Bockstael et al.
1987).

1. Estimated Aggregate Willingness to Pay for Water Quality Acceptable for Swimming in
the Entire Bay* (1984$)
Users
Non-users
$43 to $81 million
$17 to $26 million
Total              $60 to $107 million

*Population in Washington, DC, and Baltimore SMSAs

2. Aggregate Benefits/Losses to Users From Changes in Chesapeake Bay Water Quality,
by Beach (1984)
Beach
             Scenarios (Ranges)
             (millions of dollars)
improvement improvement 20% degradation
   20%        10%
 Sandy Point         $8 - $14
 Chesapeake Beach    $1 - $4
 Point Lookout       $1 - $2
             $3 - $6       $5 - $8
             $0.2-$2     $0.1-$1
             $0.4-$0.6    $0.1-$0.2
 3. Aggregate Benefits for Three Water-Related Activities from a "20%" Improvement in
 the Chesapeake Bay's Water Quality (1984$)
 Activity

 Public western shore beach use
 Boating with trailered boats
 Striped bass sportfishing
                          Benefit Range

             $8.3 to $22.6 million (1984 data)
             $0.6 to $7.1 million (1983 data)
             $0.5 to $1.5 million (1980 data)
                                        D-25

-------
                                       References

 Arrow, K.  et al.  1993.  "Report of the NOAA Panel on Contingent Valuation."  U.S.
 Department of Commerce, National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration. Rockville, MD.
 January 11, 1993.

 Bockstael, N. et al. 1987.  "Benefit Analysis Using Indirect or Imputed Market Methods." CR
 811043.  Prepared for EPA Office of Policy, Planning and Evaluation.

 Bondelid, T. and W.S. Cooter.  1994. "A Tool for Evaluating the Effectiveness of the Clean
 Water Act."  Research Triangle Institute Project No. 35U-5726-3, Center for Environmental
 Analysis, Research Triangle Institute, P.O. Box 12194, Research Triangle Park, NC 27709.
 Bondelid, T., W.S. Cooter, and M.J. Kealy. 1994.  "How Much Has Water Quality Improved
 Due to Investments in Water Pollution Controls?" Draft working paper.

 Cambridge Economics. 1992.   "Contingent Valuation. A Critical Assessment."  Cambridge,
 MA.

 Carson, R.T. and R.C. Mitchell. 1991. "The Value of Clean Water: The Public's Willingness
 to Pay for Boatable,  Fishable,  and Swimmable Quality Water."  Mimeograph, Economics
 Department, University of California, San Diego.

 Carson, R.T. and R.C. Mitchell. 1993. "The Value of Clean Water: The Public's Willingness
 to Pay for Boatable,  Fishable, and Swimmable Quality Water." Water Resources Research.
 29(7): 2445-2454.

 Crowder.  1987.  "Economic Costs of Reservoir Sedimentation."  Journal of Soil and Water
 Conservation.

 Cummings, R. and G. Harrison. 1991. "Identifying and Measuring Nonuse Values for Natural
 and Environmental Resources: A Critical Review of the State of the Art."  Final Report. April
 1991.

 EPA. 1983.  "Health Effects Criteria for Marine Recreational Waters." Health Effects Research
 Labs, Office of Research and Development, August  1983.

 EPA. 1990.  "Environmental Investments: The Costs of a Clean Environment."  EPA-230-11-
 90-083. EPA Office of Policy, Planning and Evaluation.  November 1990.

 EPA. 1993. "National Water Quality Inventory: 1992 Report to Congress." Draft Report.
 EPA Office of Water, Washington, D.C.

EPA and Resources for the Future. 1993a.  "Clean Water and  the American  Economy."
Proceedings: Surface Water, Volume 1. EPA-800-R-93-001a. EPA Office of Water.  March
 1993.
                                       D-26

-------
EPA. 1993b.  "International Trade in Environmental Protection Equipment. An Assessment of
Existing Data."  EPA-230-R-93-006.  EPA Office of Policy, Planning and Evaluation. My
1993.

Freeman,III, A.M. 1982.  "Air and Water Pollution Control: A Benefit-Cost Assessment."
Wiley Press. New York, NY.

Freeman III, A.M. 1993.  "The Economics of Valuing Marine Recreation: A Review of the
Empirical Evidence," Economics Working Paper 93-102, Bowdoin College, Brunswick, ME.

Kealy, M.J. 1994.  "Benefits of Investments in Clean Water." Darft paper.  EPA Office of
Policy, Planning and Evaluation, February 1994.

Lyon, R. and S. Farrow. 1992. "An Economic Analysis of Clean Water Act Issues: Preliminary
Results." Office of Management and Budget. February 1992.

Mitchell, R.C. and R.T. Carson. 1984. "Willingness to Pay for  National Freshwater Quality
Improvements."  CR 810224-01.  EPA, Washington, DC.

Mitchell, R.C. and R.T. Carson. 1986.  "The Use of Contingent Valuation Data for Benefit/Cost
Analysis in Water Pollution Control."  CR 810224-02. EPA, Washington, DC.

Mitchell, R.C. and R.T. Carson.  1989. "Using Surveys to Value Benefits for Public Goods."
Resources for the Future, Washington, DC.

Morris, G.E. and R.A. Cushman. 1993. "Benefits of Improved Water Quality to Diversionary
Users: Phase I Assessment."  Project No. 35U- 5726-3FR.   Center for Economic Research,
Research Triangle Park, NC.

National Park Service. "1982-1983 Nationwide Recreation Survey." April 1986.

National Research Council. 1993.  "Managing Wastewater in Coastal Urban Areas."  National
Academy of Science, Washington DC.

Strand, I. 1993.  "The Contribution of Clean Water to Commercial Fisheries." in  Proceedings
of the Clean Water and the American Economy Conference.   EPA 800-R-93-001a, EPA,
Washington, DC.

U. S. Department of Commerce. 1991.  " 1990 National Shellfish Register of Classified Estuarine
Waters." NOAA, July 1991.
                                       D-27

-------

-------

-------

-------

-------
o g) n
             oT
    m
o  :S.
       —    —. <_i  O
     ,2.    O
                    CD
   < to
             a    s»
             o    -o

             8    §
             Ji.    CD
             05    2.
             O    =:•
                   
-------