-------
regulation are so great that an individual facility is no longer profitable. In addition to lost
profits, closures could lead to secondary impacts such as:
• Losses in employment
• Losses in government tax revenues
• Adverse effects on small business
• Losses in paper or pulp production capacity, leading to:
Supply/demand adjustments and product pricing shifts
Negative impacts on the U.S. foreign trade account
Facility closures are estimated by comparing the mill's "salvage value" to the present value
of its future earnings. The salvage value represents the expected amount of cash the owner
would receive if the mill were closed and liquidated. The present value represents the value in
current dollars of the expected stream of earnings that the mill can generate. If the salvage
value of the mill is greater than the earnings the mill is expected to generate, then the owner
presumably would liquidate the mill rather than operate it.7 Figure 3-3 provides a schematic
diagram of the methodology and components used in the closure analysis. Sections 3.2.1.1 and
3.2.1.2 describe the calculation of the salvage value and the present value of future earnings,
respectively. Section 3.2.1.3 describes a sample closure analysis. Section 3.2.1.4 discusses the
scoring methodology used to project closure, and Section 3.1.2.5 reviews the reasons mills could
be identified as closures before any incremental pollution control costs are incurred (i.e., baseline
closures).
7Whcn a mill is liquidated for its salvage value, the Agency assumes that the mill no longer is
operated; thus, closure-related impacts could result. In contrast, mills that are sold because a
new owner presumably can generate a greater return are considered transfers. Transfers cause no
closure-related impacts, even if the transfer was prompted by increased regulatory costs.
Transfers arc not estimated in this analysis.
3-22
-------
Incremental
Capital Costs
Assessed Value of
Land, Buildings, and
Equipment
Book Value of:
Land
Buildings
Equipment
Less Cum. Depreciation
Equipment Lifetime
Discount Rate
Depreciation Rates
Tax Rates
Present Value of
Plant Cash Flows
vs.
Salvage
Value
Discount Rate
majsi
Forecasted Cash Flow
Streams
Analysis of Recent
Industry Trends,
Impacts of Other
Recent Regulations
Figure 3-3. Overview of closure analysis methodology.
3-23
-------
3.2.1.1 Salvage Value
The salvage value is calculated assuming the mill will be closed. Thus, assets are
evaluated based not on their potential for contributing to operations, but only on their market
value in a liquidation sale of plant and equipment. Salvage value is estimated assuming that all
cash transactions are realized in the current year and that discounting is not required. In fact,
many mills could face multiyear obligations that are not dismissed with mill closure. The salvage
value is the net cash realized by the plant owner after all assets are sold and obligations are
dismissed.
Salvage value includes the value of short-term (or current) assets and long-term and fixed
assets. Short-term assets, defined as those assets not expected to be held beyond a year, include
cash, short-term Certificates of Deposit, inventory, and other assets. Long-term assets include
financial instruments expected to be held beyond a year and fixed assets of plant, equipment, and
land.
Short-term assets held on mill balance sheets generally will be considered part of the
mill's working capital and therefore are clearly part of the mill's asset base. Long-term financial
assets, such as deferred bond expense, stocks, bonds, and intangibles, could be held on the
balance sheet of either the mill or the parent company.8 There is no method of determining
what share of the long-term financial assets of a parent company or headquarters mill should be
allocated to individual mills. These assets are also typically considered independent of normal
mill working capital or mill operations. Timberlands are considered long-term investments that
are essentially separate from the mill (i.e., they have value whether or not the mill continues to
operate). Therefore, timberlands and long-term financial assets other than land, buildings, and
equipment were excluded from the salvage value calculations. All other tangible assets (both
"The survey has separate sections for balance sheet information depending on whether the
facility is part of a multifacility operation. An independent, single-facility company would be able
to show a detailed balance sheet for the mill, while mills that belong to a multifacility company
might have components held only at the corporate level, not at the facility level. Only those
components allocated to a facility were included in the closure analysis.
3-24
-------
short- and long-term) are included in the salvage value. The most recent data in the survey
(1989) is used in the salvage value calculation.
Valuing Current Assets. Current assets include cash and near-cash financial assets,
accounts receivable, and inventories. The valuation of these assets is based on their probable
stability during an auction/liquidation process. Since cash and near-cash financial instruments
would not decline in value in the event of liquidation, they would command their face value even
in a distress sale. Accounts receivables and inventories (including both inventories of raw
materials and finished products) are likely to decline in value to some degree depending on
factors such as company and industry experience with bad debt problems, economic conditions,
and the geographic proximity of potential purchasers of raw materials or finished products.
Current assets are carried at the mill level based on their original purchase cost or, in the
case of finished goods, at the manufacturing cost. In valuing these assets, the Agency assumes
that they are made up of two components: intangibles (e.g., cash, receivables, and short-term
investments) and inventories (e.g., raw materials, supplies, fuels, work-in-progress, and finished
•goods). In the event that the facility is liquidated at an auction, these assets would be recovered
at varying proportions of their book value.
Since intangible current assets are the most liquid, the Agency assumes they would be
recovered at their face value. Unlike inventories, most intangible current assets would maintain
their book value in the event of an auction. Some items, such as CDs and other short-term
investments, actually are likely to appreciate in value compared to their cost as recorded on the
books. Accounts receivable, however, could be worth less than their book value, depending on
each mill's accounting practices for recognizing bad accounts. Overall, the Agency assumes that
the book value of these assets accurately reflects their actual market value (i.e., they are valued
at 100 percent in the salvage value calculations).
Inventories are not as marketable as the rest of current assets because of their unique or
specialized purposes. In the event of liquidation, a mill would have to sell its inventories at a
fraction of their recorded book value. For example, the demand for specialty items such as
deinking chemicals would depend on the number of nearby deinking mills that use similar
3-25
-------
processes. Such products likely could not be sold for what the mill paid to the chemical supplier.
For this reason, the analysis values inventories by applying a recovery factor that represents the
portion of book value expected to be recouped in a sale. A 40-percent recovery factor is used to
calculate the salvage value of inventories. This recovery factor reflects the fact that many of the
specialty supplies and unfinished products would have to be sold at a fraction of their book
value, while basic commodities such as finished pulp and raw materials likely would maintain
most of their value in the event of liquidation.9
Valuing Fixed Assets. Two approaches are used to estimate the value of the fixed or
long-term assets at each facility: based on the tax assessment values and based on the book
value of the fixed assets. Since neither method is always satisfactory, both are incorporated into
the closure model.
Tax Assessments. Most of the mills pay local property taxes based on the assessed value
of the mill's fixed assets. Questionnaire responses provide information about the 1989 assessed
value of each facility's land, buildings, and equipment. The questionnaire also provides the
percent of market value on which the tax assessment was based. Each facility's market value is
calculated as the facility's assessed value divided by the percent of market value rate. A 20
percent recovery factor is applied to the result to reflect the fact that the assets would be
liquidated at a fraction of their value.
Not all facilities could provide both tax assessments and percentage of market value.
Questionnaire responses indicate several possible reasons:
» Some facilities were not assessed for tax purposes.
• Some assessments included nonmill assets.
• Some assessments bore no relationship to current market value of the assets.
'Companies might maintain their inventories under a "First In First Out" (FIFO) approach or
under the "Last In First Out" (LIFO) approach. During inflationary periods, LIFO will tend to
undervalue inventories, generally as a means of limiting tax liability. The survey did not ask the
respondent to identify the inventory accounting system used; however, the system used is unlikely
to create a significant difference in the analysis.
3-26
-------
Book Value. An alternative approach for estimating the salvage value of each facility's
fixed assets is according to the most recent balance sheet. The book value of the fixed assets
(including the facility land, buildings and improvements, equipment, and machinery) can be
calculated from the survey data. The book value is equal to the recorded cost less any
accumulated depreciation. (As mentioned above, assets such as long-term investments and
timberlands are excluded from this calculation.) Similarly to the tax assessment approach, a 20
percent recovery factor is applied to the book value of the fixed assets to reflect the liquidation
value of those assets.
There are potential difficulties with using the book value of assets to estimate the salvage
value of a mill. The book value understates the true value of some assets while overstating the
value of others. For instance, a facility's land could have been purchased as long ago as the 19th
century, and has since appreciated in value tremendously. Other assets, however, such as a
cement settling tank, might have no market value, but could continue to carry a book value since
they have not yet been completely depreciated.
Summary of Salvage Value Estimates. The Agency examined the estimated salvage
values for the 317 mills that are expected to bear the costs of regulation and that can be analyzed
in the closure model. For all of these mills combined, the book value approach led to a higher
average salvage value than the tax assessment approach. When looking at individual mills,
however, the tax assessment salvage value was higher than the book value in about 3 of 10 cases
(Table 3-8).
Mill closure costs, which reduce the overall salvage value of the facility, are difficult to
estimate even by mill executives. These costs can include pension administration, payout costs,
and site cleanup prior to sale. These costs are not included in the salvage value estimate. As a
s
result, the calculated salvage value could be high, which would make the mill more likely to be
projected to close in the analysis. This approach leads to a conservative estimate of the number
of mill closures.
In summary, the closure mode! relies on two estimates of salvage value for each facility:
• Tax assessment value of fixed assets plus short-term assets
3-27
-------
TABLE 3-8
SUMMARY OF TECHNIQUES FOR DETERMINING SALVAGE VALUE
Parameter
Salvage Value (Thousands, 1989 Dollars)
Average Total
Percent of Time
Salvage Value
Estimation Approach
Produced Greater
Value
Assessment Approach:
Book Value Approach:
$38,490
$41,905
$10,854,209
$13,032,453
29%
71%
S:\ECONVPULP2\EIA\SEC 3\T3 8.WK3
24-Jun-93
3-28
-------
• Book value of fixed assets plus short-term assets
The values of fixed assets and inventories are reduced by recovery factors to reflect liquidation
values.
3.2.7.2 Present Value of Forecasted Earnings
The present value of each mill is its future stream of earnings in current dollars. The
valuation assumes that the mill continues to be used for the manufacture of paper or pulp. The
methodology uses recent earnings and other data to estimate future earnings, and then discounts
the future stream to derive the present value. The components of this analysis include measuring
earnings, establishing a time frame for the analysis, projecting earnings, discounting earnings, and
incorporating the incremental costs of regulation. In addition, Subchapter S corporations require
separate consideration because income is taxed at the rate for individuals, not corporations.
Definition of Economic Earnings. Two alternatives were examined to estimate the
present value of future plant operations:
Net income, calculated as revenues less manufacturing cost of goods sold; selling,
general, and administrative expenses; depreciation; interest; and taxes.
Cash flow, which equals net income plus depreciation.
Estimates of the present value generated from future plant operations generally are based on
cash flow projections. Depreciation is added to net income because it reflects previous, rather
than current, spending and does not actually absorb any portion of incoming revenues.
Net income figures also can be used to project the value of continued plant operations.
This approach assumes that ongoing reinvestment in plant and equipment will be necessary and
that in the long run, depreciation costs should be reflected as a charge against earnings (i.e.,
annual maintenance is not sufficient to ensure a mill's efficiency and capacity in the long run).
This approach was chosen to reflect the continuing capital investment and expansion seen for the
3-29
-------
majority of mills in the survey (see Section 2.4.4)—the more conservative indicator of the future
value of continued plant operations. This approach, however, might overestimate the potential
closures of newer plants, which would report higher depreciation figures (i.e., the required
investment is overstated) and thus lower earnings. These facilities might appear less
economically viable than they actually are in such an analysis.
In the closure model, the present value of future earnings is calculated based on net
Income. For independent facilities, earnings generated from long-term investments are not
included. These revenues (identified in survey responses) are considered to be independent from
the mill's paper and pulp production. Furthermore, since the assets generating these revenues
are excluded from the salvage value calculation, their earnings should not be included on the
opposite side of the closure equation.
Time Frame for Analysis. The capital expenditures associated with additional pollution
control for the pulp and paper industry are depreciated over a 15-year lifetime in the cost
annualization model (see Section 3.1.1). The same time frame is used for the present value
analysis.
Earnings Forecast. Three methods are used to forecast future earnings. All three
methods are based on the 1985, 1988, and 1989 data collected in the survey and all use the same
general set of assumptions and procedures:
No cost pass-through. The mill is assumed to be unable to raise prices to recoup
incremental pollution control costs. It is as if there is a foreign supply waiting at
the U.S. border; if domestic mills raise their prices, imports will flood into the
domestic market.
No growth. The mill is assumed to be running at or near capacity and significant
growth is considered unlikely without a major capacity addition.
Constant 1989 dollars. Data from 1985 and 1988 are inflated using the change in
the Consumer Price Index (see Table 3-2).
3-30
-------
Earnings for 1986 and 1987. Earnings from 1985, 1988, and 1989 were regressed
to estimate 1986 and 1987 earnings. If no 1985 data were available, the earnings
were set to zero for that year.10
Tax rate applied, if necessary, to obtain after-tax earnings. For facilities that are
part of multiple-facility companies, earnings are estimated as revenues minus
costs. These amounts are adjusted to after-tax earnings using tax rates for
corporate income shown in Section 2 of the questionnaire for the business entity.
For independent facilities, net income is taken from the income statement and
does not need to be adjusted. For S-Corporations, after-tax earnings are
estimated using personal tax rates.11
The three forecasting methods can be summarized as follows:
• Simple Cycle
Peak year of cycle is 1989, based on industry data.
Data for 1985 to 1989 are repeated in mirror image to provide cycle.
Advantage: Stays closest to survey data, retains cyclical nature of industry.
Disadvantage: Does not account for what happened in 1990 and 1991, at
least not on an industry-wide basis.
• Moving Average
Data for 1990 and 1991 are generated by scaling 1989 earnings based on
industry-wide decline rates.
Data for 1992 to 2011 generated as a 7-year moving average.
Advantage: Data for 1990 and 1991 incorporate more information than
simple cycle method.
Disadvantage: Moving average dampens industry cycle.
• Modified Cycle
Data for 1990 and 1991 are generated by scaling 1989 earnings based on
industry-wide decline rates.
'"Where 1985 earnings were available in the survey data; about half the entries were positive
and half were negative (i.e.. the facility suffered a loss). Thus, in the absence of survey data , a
value of zero is a reasonable estimate of 1985 revenues for a facility.
"A facility's operating losses, like earnings, are reduced by the tax shield. The owner may
use the operating loss to offset income from another facility or carry the loss forward to offset
income generated in the future. For mills owned by muititacility companies, the closure model
selects a federal tax rate based on the parent's marginal income tax rate. If the parent shows a
loss, logic implies a 0-percent tax rate. The fact that a parent company has net losses should not
imply that a mill's earnings arc tax-free. The closure model uses a marginal federal tax rate of
34 percent for mills whose parent shows a net loss. The 34-percent bracket was the most
representative for companies in the closure analysis.
3-31
-------
Data for 1985 to 1991 are repeated for 1992 to 1998 and from 1999 to
2005.
Advantage: Data for 1990 and 1991 incorporate more information than
simple cycle method, retains cyclical nature of industry.
Disadvantage: Sharp shifts are seen between cycles; could be interpreted
as sharp management action to correct the mill's financial performance.
These forecasting methods reflect both smoothed and unsmoothed approaches to modeling the
cyclical nature of the paper and pulp industry.12 In the moving average and modified cycle
methods, earnings for 1990 and 1991 are scaled from 1989 data using the industry-wide decline in
profits shown in Mies et al., 1992. Decline rates used in the calculations are 30.7 percent (for
1990) and 28.0 percent (for 1991).
Figure 3-4 illustrates the three forecasting methods. The survey data are the points
shown for 1985,1988, and 1989 (Figure 3-4, right side). The data for 1986 and 1987 are
obtained by regressing the 1985, 1988, and 1989 data. These five values form the basis for the
forecasted values (Figure 3-4, left side).
For the simple cycle, the value for 1988 is repeated for 1990, 1996, 1998, 2004, and 2008.
The forecasted sequence has two peaks, 1997 and 2005, and two low points, 1993 and 2001. The
data for 1990 and 1991 are the same for the moving average and modified cycle
approaches—both are scaled by the industry decline rates. The moving average approach rapidly
smooths the fluctuations of the business cycle to a near-horizontal line. The modified cycle has
timing differences from the simplified cycle—there are two peaks, 1996 and 2003, but three low
points, 1992, 1999, and 2006. While Figure 3-4 illustrates a typical pattern seen in the survey
data, a wide range of possible patterns exist. Because of the uncertainty about the choice of
forecasting models and potential outcomes, a methodology was developed to incorporate all
three forecasting methods in the closure analysis (Section 3.2.1.3).
12Other parameters, such as gross domestic product and population, are not included in the
forecasting model because they arc measured on a national basis while the forecasts are done on
a facility basis. For example, a population increase may lead to increased paper demand, but the
mill cannot increase its output beyond its capacity.
3-32
-------
52 «3
ro *±
o to
a>O
a) cc
^ra
^Q
CO
\
\
\
\
\
o
>>
O
•a
cc
2
CD
O)
c
o
CO
T3
O
•4—1
(D
o
on
_
o
>*
o
JO)
a.
CO
o
in
o
o
O
in
(000)$ u| '
3-33
-------
Discounting. The final step in estimating each mill's baseline present value is to discount
the earnings stream back to current dollars. This step does not adjust the stream for
inflation,since the earnings projections are in real terms. Thus, the discount rate used for
discounting must be a real discount rate, obtained by subtracting the estimated annual rate of
inflation (see Table 3-2) from the nominal discount rate. The same requirement used in the cost
annualization model (i.e., the discount rate must be between 5 and 19 percent) is used in the
calculating the present value of future earnings.
Summary of Forecasting Earnings. In summary, three estimates of earnings are used in
the closure model:
» Moving average
• Simple cycle
• Modified cycle
The Agency examined the present value of future earnings as calculated by the three
forecasting methods for the 317 mills that are estimated to bear regulatory costs and are in the
closure analysis. Table 3-9 summarizes the results. The moving average method results in the
highest average present value and, in more than half the cases, the highest present value for an
individual mill. This result is expected because the moving average dampens out the business
cycle (see Figure 3-4). For almost all the remaining cases, the simple cycle method results in the
highest present value for an individual mill. The modified cycle results in the highest present
value for a mill in only 1 percent of the cases. The modified cycle method also h ••.<•. the lowest
average present value.
The three forecasting methods produce average present values of future earnings vhat are
within 13 percent of each other. For specific facilities, the estimates can show a wider variation.
Since the determination of whether a facility is likely to close is a comparison of the salvage
value and value of .future earnings, the choice of a forecasting method may affect whether the
facility of projected to close. The choice of a forecasting method may also change the closure
determination if there is very little margin between the salvage value and post-regulatory future
3-34
-------
TABLE 3-9
SUMMARY OF TECHNIQUES FOR DETERMINING FORECASTED EARNINGS
Present Value of Forecasted Earnings
(Thousands, 1989 Dollars)
Parameter
Average
Total
Percent of Time
Forecasting
Method Produced
Highest
Estimate
Simple Cycle:
Moving Average:
Modified Cycle:
$160,503
$164,256
$142,026
$51,039,796
$49,052,970
$45,164,127
62%
37%
1%
S:\ECON\PULP2\EIA\SEC 3\T3 9.WK3
24-Jun-93
3-35
-------
earnings. For these reasons, the closure analysis incorporates all three forecasting methods in
the evaluation of facility closure.
3.2.L3 Sample Closure Analysis
Table 3-10 cross-references the data used in the closure analysis with the survey data.
Figures 3-5a and 3-5b are an annotated printout of the closure model based on hypothetical data.
When actually used, however, the closure model output closely resembles Figures 3-5a and 3-5b,
and contains facility-specific confidential information.
In Figure 3-5a, the section labeled "A" contains input variables for the calculation. The
estimated inflation rate is based on the change in the Consumer Price Index from 1981 to 1991
(Table 3-2). The company-specific discount rate is taken from survey data. The average
discount rate is calculated from the survey data based on company discount rates that fall
between 5 and 19 percent. The next line shows the nominal discount rate used in the present
value calculations. The real discount rate is calculated as the nominal discount rate minus
inflation. Recovery factors for inventories and fixed assets are given as 40 and 20 percent,
respectively. The company tax structure is used to identify which set of tax rates should be used
to calculate after-tax income. In the example, the facility's tax rate is based on the income level
of the company that owns the mill. For an independent facility, the net income does not need to
be adjusted for taxes. For an S Corporation, personal income tax rates are used (CCH, 1991a).
The average state tax rate is added to federal tax rate to provide the combined effective tax ratd
for the mill.
Two methods were used to calculate the salvage value of a mill: tax assessment and book
value. Salvage values for the mill are calculated in Section B of Figure 3-5a. (Note that all
values are expressed in thousands of dollars.) The salvage value of currents assets is: $30,000 +
($62,000 x 40%) = $54,800. Under the tax assessment method, the mill's salvage value is
$36,000, which is 20 percent of its market value, $180,000. The book value of the mill is the sum
of the book value for the individual components minus the cumulative depreciation ($6,500 +
3-36
-------
TABLE 3-10
COMPONENTS USED IN THE CLOSURE ANALYSIS
Description
Location in Questionnaire
Multifacility Independent
SAS File Member Name
Multifacility Independent
SALVAGE VALUE COMPONENTS:
1989 Book Value of Current Assets 57a
1989 Book Value of Inventories 57b
1 989 Assessed Value of Fixed Assets 77d
Percent of Market Value 78
1989 Book Value of Land 58e
1 989 Book Value of Buildings 58g
1989 Book Value of Equipment 58h
1 989 Cumulative Depreciation 58j
1 989 Book Value of Other NC Assets 58i
EARNINGS COMPONENTS:
Independents:
Net Income
1985
1988
1989
Other Income:
1985
1988
1989
45a
45b
77d
78
46d
46f
46g
46k
46h-j
B3C
B3C
BSD
BSD
B3C
B3C
B3C
B3C
B3C
B3B
B3B
BSD
BSD
B3B
B3B
B3B
B3B
B3B
16k
19k
22k
16b
19b
22b
B2B
B2B
B2B
B2B
B2B
B2B
Multis:
Revenues
1985
1988
1989
Manufacturing Costs
1985
1988
1989
Non-Manufacturing Costs
1985
1988
1989
Company Discount Rate
65 (1985)
65 (1988)
65 (1989)
68
71
74
69a
72a
75a
13
35
BSD
BSD
BSD
BSD
BSD
BSD
BSD
BSD
BSD
B2A
B3A
s:\econ\.\sec 3\t3 10
24-Jun-93
3-37
-------
CONFIDENTIAL BUSINESS INFORMATION
CLOSURE MODEL
Survey 10$:
ALL FIGURES IN THOUSANDS OF DOLLARS
INPUT VARIABLES:
Inflation Rate (1990-2011):
Co.-Specific Discount Rate (HOOT.):
Avg. Discount Rate (Nominal):
Nominal Discount Rate:
Seal Discount Rate:
Inventory Recovery Factor:
Fixed Asset Recovery Factor:
Company Tax Structure:
Taxable Income (Corp. Parent):
federal Income Tax Rate:
Avg. State Income Tax Rate:
Combined Eff. Income Tax Rate:
1234 Class:
4.0X
14X
13.0*
14.OX
10.OX
40.OX
20.0X
1
800,000
34.OX
6.8X
40. SZ
BAT
run date: Zfl-Jun-93
Federal Corp. Tax Table:
Taxable Average
Income Effective
($000) Tax Rate
$0 15. OX
$50 16.7X
$75 20. 4X
$100 28.3X
$335 34. OX
Federal Personal Tax Table:
Taxable Average
Income Effective
($000) Tax Rate
$0 15.0X
$20 21 .5%
$47 30. 5X
$93 31. OX
(1=Multi; 2»Independent; 3=S-Corp.)
(what if '85 income: is in different bracket than '88 £ '89)
Q SALVAGE VALUE:
CURRENT ASSETS:
1989 Cash: 30,000
19S9 Inventories: 62,000
Total: $54,800
FIXED ASSETS:
Tax Assessed Value:
Total CbOTTD):
Book: Value:
1989 Land:
1989 Buildings:
1989 Equipment:
Less Cm. Deprec.:
Total:
Recoverable Value:
Assessed Assessment Market Recoverable
Value Rate Value Value
183,000 100X $180,000 $36,COC
6,500
62,000
820,000
310,000
.$578,500
$115,700
TOTAL SALVAGE VALUE OF MILL:
Using Tax Assessments: $90.800
Using Boole Value: $170,500
Need to examine notes sections to see if assessment rate« vary for real assets vs. fixed assets.
Figure 3-5a. Closure analysis model—Inputs and salvage value using hypothetical data.
3-38
-------
PRESENT VALUE:
PAST EARNINGS ($1989):
Corporate Tax Structure:
Hulti-facilityCo.
Estimated
Estimated
FORECASTED El
Earnings
Earnings
Earnings
Earnings
Earnings
THINGS:
1985
1988
1989
1986
1987
Pre-Tax
<50,000)
120,000
150,000
$4,615
$56,154
Post-Tax
($29,625)
$71,100
$88,875
$2,735
$33,271
Regression Output:
Constant
Std Err of
R Squared
T Est
No. of Observations
Degrees of
Freedom
-1.026+08
15689.291
0.9894203
3
1
X Coeff icient(s) 51538.462
rear
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
'
>
t
(
\
{
1
4
I
BASELINE PRESENT VALUE:
SUMMARY:
Cycle
f($29,625>
J2,735
$33,271
> $71,100
$88,875
k $71, 100
$33,271
$2,735
(529,625)
$2,735
, $33,271
$71,100
k $88,875
$71,100
$33,271
$2,735
($29,625)
$2,735
$33,271
'$71,100
k $88,875
$71,100
$33,271
$2,735
K$29,625)
$2,735
$33,271
$266,661
Assessment:
Regulatory Option
Baseline
Option 2
Option 3
Option 4
Option 5
Ootion 6
Dot i on 7
Option 8
Option 9
Opt i on 10
Option 11
PV of
Incremental
Reg. Costs
SO
850
2,500
5,000
10,000
25,000
50,000
75.000
100,000
150,000
226,000
Cycle
$266,861
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
1
Avg.
<$29,625)
$2,735
$33,271
$71,100
$88,875
$61,590
$44,345
$38,899
$48,688
$55,253
$58,393
$56,577
$51,964
$50,588
$51,480
$53,278
$53,933
$53,745
$53,081
$52,581
$52,669
$52,967
$53,179
$53,165
$53,055
$52,957
$52,939
$416,898
$90,800
Cycle2 Std Err of
($29,625) \
$2,735
$33,271
$71,100
$88,875
$61,590
$44,345 >
($29,625) <
$2,735
$33,271
$71,100
$88,875
$61,590
$44,345 <
C$29,625) '
S2,735
$33,271
$71,100
$68,875
$61,590
$44,345 '
f
($29,625) *
$2,735
$33,27t
$71,100
$88,875
$61,590
$288,859
Salvage Value:
Book:
Present Value:
Coef. 5329.3871
$170,500
Mov. Avg. Mod Cycle Cycle Nov. Avg. Hod Cycle
$416,898
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
$288,859 $266,861
0 0
0 0
0 0
0 0
0 0
0 0
0 0
0 0
0 1
0 1
1 1
$416,898 S2BB.859
0 0
0 0
0 0
0 0
0 0
0 0
0 0
0 0
0 0
0 1
0 1
Closures
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
1
2
A
Figure 3-5b. Forecasted earnings and closure score using hypothetical data.
3-39
-------
$62,000 + $820,000 - $310,000 = $578,500). Liquidation value is 20 percent of the book value:
$115,700. The total salvage value for the mill is:
• Tax assessment = $54,800 + $36,000 = $90,800
• Book value = $54,800 + $115,700 = $170,500
Earnings are forecasted in Section C of Figure 3-5b. The first three lines list the earnings
for 1985, 1988, and 1989 as taken from the survey. The three pretax values are regressed, and
the values for 1986 and 1987 are calculated. Because the example mill part of a multifacility
company, the earnings (revenues minus costs) must be adjusted to posttax earnings. The present
value is calculated for each of the forecasted earnings streams using the discount rate in
Section A.
The simple cycle uses data from 1985 to 1989 in mirror-image fashion, as indicated by the
brackets. There are two peaks, 1997 and 2005, and two low points, marked by dots at 1993 and
2001. For the moving average and modified cycle, the data for 1990 and 1991 are scaled using
industry decline factors. The moving average is calculated on a 7-year basis (i.e., the value for
1992 is the average for 1985 through 1991. The modified cycle repeats the values for the 1985-
1991 period. There are two peaks, 1996 and 2003, and three low points, marked by dots at 1992,
1999, and 2006.
Section D of Figure 3-5b summarizes the results of the closure analysis. Each row,
beginning with the one entitled "Baseline," represents a regulatory alternative or option. The
present value of the incremental regulatory cost for each option is calculated with the cost
annualization model (Section 3.1, Table 3-1). With two methods of estimating salvage value
(book and tax assessment) and three methods of estimating the present value of future earnings
(simple cycle, moving average, and modified cycle), there are six ways to evaluate facility closure.
The post-regulatory earnings are calculated by subtracting the present value of incremental
regulatory costs from the present value of projected earnings. For example, under Option 9, the
present value of the post-regulatory earning is $266,861 - $100,000 = $166,861 for the simple
cycle method of projecting earnings. This value is greater than the salvage value as calculated by
the tax assessment method ($90,800) but lower than the salvage value as calculated by book value
3-40
-------
($170,500). A mill that is determined not to close under a particular combination is given a
score of 0 for that combination. A mill that is determined to close under a particular
combination is given a score of 1 for that combination. The scores are then totaled for all
combinations. Under Option 9, the simple cycle/tax assessment combination has a score of 0,
while the simple cycle/book value combination has a score of 1. The right-hand column sums the
entries for all six earnings projections/salvage value combinations to provide a closure score. The
closure score for a given facility, then, can range from 0 (no closure under any combination) to 6
(closures under all combinations).
3.2.1.4 Scoring Method for Projecting Facility Closure
The last step in the closure analysis is to evaluate when a mill would be considered a
closure. The closure score for a mill can range from 0 to 6. As mentioned earlier, there could
be difficulties with a particular mill's data or estimation methods. For this reason, the mills with
closure scores of 1 or 2 are not considered closures. A score of 4 or higher in the closure model
is considered a facility closure. A score of 4 or higher results from the salvage value exceeding
the post-regulatory projected earnings under at least two forecasting methods and both methods
of estimating salvage value. Under these circumstances, the Agency assumes the mill would
close. In the example given in Figure 3-5di the mill experiences adverse financial impacts
beginning with Option 9, but is not considered a closure until Option 11.
For mills with no tax assessment salvage value, however, a score of 3 predicts closure. A
mill with a score of 3 would have scored 1 for every combination of forecasting method and book
value for salvage value estimate, and the Agency assumed that, if a tax assessment were available,
the mill would be likely to close under at least one forecasting method/tax assessment for salvage
value combination.
3-41
-------
3.2.1.5 Baseline Closures
A baseline closure is a mill that fails the salvage value test before the addition of
incremental pollution control costs. Section 2.4.5 of the industry profile identified a category of
mills that is likely to appear as baseline closures. These are "captive" mills—mills that exist to
serve other facilities under the same ownership. In the entire mill population, between 46 and 51
mills reported that over 90 percent of all pulp, paper, and paperboard revenues were from
transfers to other facilities under the same ownership. In addition to these captive mills, between
56 to 60 mills indicated that 90 percent or more of their revenues from one product (pulp, paper,
or paperboard) were from transfers to other facilities under the same ownership. Over half of
the mills indicated they transferred some product to other facilities under the same ownership
during the survey period.
Since many of the transfers are done at cost, these captive and near-captive mills would
show little, if any, profit. If the captive mills have any salvage value, they could be deemed
closures before the addition of incremental pollution control costs. In actuality, these mills
would not close but would raise the transfer prices for their products to meet the incremental
costs of pollution control; they should not be considered as closures due to the incremental cost
of regulation.
Of the 338 mills estimated to bear incremental costs in this rulemaking, data were
available to perform the closure analysis on 317. About 84 of these 317 mills are considered
baseline closures. Nearly 40 percent of the baseline closures (31 mills) show anywhere from 1 to
3 years of losses, fourteen mills show only minimal profits. (The earnings for these mills might
be more favorable if we examined cash flow rather than net income.) Sixteen mills are
considered "captive" mills. Fifteen mills had high salvage values because of their large amounts
of cash. (Current assets, other than inventory, are valued at 100 percent while all other
components in the salvage value are reduced by a recovery factor.) These mills are unlikely to
close even though the salvage value exceeds the present value of future earnings.
In other words, the industry profile identified a category of mills likely to appear as
baseline closures before the closure analysis was performed. Given the widespread practice of
3-42
-------
transferring product to other mills under the same ownership, low earnings may be a frequent
phenomenon in the survey data. The methodological choice of analyzing net income rather than
cash flow for projected earnings also results in low earnings projections. The analysis of the
baseline closure results also identified a small number of mills whose large cash positions led to
high salvage values, which in turn, resulted in the mills considered as baseline closures. In
summary, a mill could be a baseline closure for a wide range of reasons. The projection of
baseline closures is consistent with the industry structure as seen in the survey data and the
methodology chosen for the financial analysis. The objective of the closure analysis, however, is
to examine the impacts of additional pollution control costs on the pulp and paper industry. To
examine impacts, only the incremental closures (i.e., beyond baseline) are counted because these
closures can be attributed solely to the incremental costs of compliance.
3.2.2 Ratio Analysis
Financial ratios represent an accepted method for evaluating financial performance and
health. For example, investors and lenders often use ratios to determine whether a firm is
creditworthy. Managers use ratios to help build strategies for capital investment, mergers and
acquisitions, pricing, or any other decision that could affect the firm's financial structure.
Similarly, in an investigation of regulatory compliance costs, ratio analysis can provide insight
into how additional pollution control requirements will affect the financial structure of mills. In
contrast to the closure model discussed in Section 3.2.1, financial ratio analysis identifies
economic impacts on facilities and companies that are less severe than closure.
In ratio analysis, standard financial data arc translated into statistics that allow for
comparison of the health of reporting entities or groups of entities. Financial health comparisons
are based on profitability, leverage, liquidity, and other relevant characteristics.
Pulp and paper firms might make capital expenditures and incur annual operating and
maintenance costs associated with additional levels of pollution control. These investments,
which might not contribute to product quality or output level, could adversely affect their
financial structure. The magnitude of such impacts depends on the size of the investment
3-43
-------
required, the size of the firm, and the method of financing. Furthermore, the size of the
investment, or the cost of compliance, is often a function of the products produced, the current
equipment and processes used, and the new level of control required.
Data gathered in the survey are used to develop a financial profile of the industry's
facilities and firms. The cost of additional pollution control is then combined with the balance
sheet information under two alternative financing options (i.e., long-term debt and working
capital). A pre- and post-regulation ratio analysis of the facilities and companies is used to
compare the financial health of the firms before regulation and under alternative regulatory
options.
3.2.2.1 Financial Ratios
To derive an accurate financial profile of the industry, a variety of financial ratios are
used. Several measures of economic impacts often must be examined to obtain a clear picture of
the regulation's potential effects. The ratios to be used in the analysis cover three basic aspects
of the financial structure and health of a facility or firm:
• Profitability
• Leverage
• Liquidity/solvency
Profitability Ratios. Profitability ratios measure the company's ability to make a profit
relative to the size of its sales, stockholders investment (equity), and capital investments (assets).
Examples of profitability ratios include net income margin, return on equity, and return on
assets.
Net Income Margin. Net income margin measures the percentage of sales revenue that is
converted into profit. Net income, for this analysis, will be calculated as earnings after interest
and taxes. This ratio is a good indicator of profitability to use when comparing the regulatory
3-44
-------
effects on prices. For instance, knowing that a firm converts $0.22 of every $1.00 in sales to
profit helps assess its ability to absorb additional pollution control costs without a price increase.
The larger the margin, the greater the facility's ability to absorb increased costs and still remain
profitable. This ratio will be calculated from survey data at the business-entity level and, for
independent single-facility entities, at the facility level.
Return on Assets. Return on assets (ROA) measures the firm's efficiency in using assets
to generate profits. An ROA of 18 percent indicates that, $0.18 in profit is generated for every
$1.00 in assets. ROA reflects differences in leverage as well as in profitability because high
interest payments to finance assets can result in lower taxes." ROA is used in the analysis
i
because it can be calculated for both the facility level and the business level.14
Leverage Ratios. Leverage measures the level of debt a firm uses to finance its
operations. Investment in additional pollution control equipment could affect a firm's leverage if
additional debt is taken on to finance pollution control equipment. The reduction in leverage
due to investment in pollution control could affect the firm's financial flexibility. In general, a
highly leveraged firm has less flexibility to ride out a market downturn; similarly, it would not
have the resources to take advantage of opportunities for upgrading, expansion, or acquisition.
"The Agency considered using return on equity (ROE) in the financial analysis. ROE
measures how effectively the company creates value for the equity holders. An ROE of 18
percent indicates that for every $1.00 of equity invested in a firm's assets, $0.18 of net income is
generated. This ratio measures the firm's efficiency in using invested money to generate profits.
ROA and ROE highly correlated, i.e., they tend to move together, (see Brealy asd-Myers", 1984,
pp. 580). Using both variables would not provide much additional information. Because equity
information needed to calculate ROE is generally not held at the facility level and because equity
information for common shareholders only is not available for most organizations, the Agency
did not use ROE in the financial analysis.
'"At the business entity level, ROA is calculated as net income/total assets. At the facility
level, it is calculated as (revenues - manufacturing costs - nonmanufacturing costs)/total assets,
because taxes and interest are rarely kept at the facility level. Technically, interest tax shields
should be removed from cash flows and an average of assets from the beginning of the year to
yearend should be used when calculating ROA values. Since neither parameter is available from
the survey, however, these adjustments arc not included. The analysis focuses on the change in
the ratio due to incremental pollution control costs, rather than fine-tuning the baseline
estimates.
3-45
-------
Instead, such a firm would be committed to making interest payments on its debt, thus
minimizing outlays for ongoing operations or expansions.
Times Interest Earned. The times interest earned (TIE) ratio measures the amount of
interest payments a firm must make in relation to its cash flows. The TIE ratio is calculated as
follows:
TIE = [Earnings before interest and taxes (EBIT) + depreciation] 4- interest expense
For'example, a firm with a TIE ratio of 5.0 has cash flows sufficient to cover a five-fold increase
in interest expense.
Debt Ratio. The debt ratio, as calculated in this analysis, is the proportion of total debt
to total assets. Total debt will be calculated as the sum of all liabilities. This ratio is a common
indicator of the degree to which debt is used to finance the assets of the company.
Considered in conjunction with one another, these two ratios provide a good picture of a
firm's leverage. A firm with an above-average debt ratio, for example, might be very profitable
and thus have a high TIE ratio. In this case, the high level of debt might present no problems.
Conversely, a low debt ratio might make a firm appear healthy; but if it also has a low TIE ratio,
problems could arise when the firm incurs additional debt.
Liquidity/Solvency Ratios. The third group of ratios assesses firm liquidity and near-term
solvency. They describe a firm's ability to meet its short-term financing needs using its own
short-term resources. Liquidity can affect a firm's ability to raise capital, since lenders are
concerned with a borrower's ability to meet payments on a day-to-day basis. The liquidity of
pulp and paper manufacturers should be examined, since any use of current assets to finance
pollution control equipment, or the operation of that equipment, could significantly reduce
liquidity.
Current Ratio. The current ratio, calculated as the proportion of current assets to current
liabilities, indicates whether a firm can cover its current obligations using its available cash or
3-46
-------
liquid assets. Firms opting to finance pollution control equipment with working capital could see
their current ratio decline dramatically. Easy to calculate, this ratio provides a very common and
accurate tool with which to assess the impacts of the proposed regulations.15
Net working capital. Net working capital is the difference between current assets and
current liabilities, and represents the amount of cash or liquid assets that a firm or facility has
available for short-term operations. If pollution control costs are paid by internal funding, net
working capital will be affected.
Net working capital to total assets. Dividing net working capital by total assets creates a
ratio to evaluate the potential for future investment compared to past investment.
Summary. Table 3-11 displays the seven financial ratios discussed above and shows how
each is calculated. A preliminary selection of these ratios for consideration in this analysis was
made based on their potential usefulness in evaluating the effects of the proposed regulations.
Together, these ratios will provide insight into the three key aspects of firms' and facilities'
financial structure—profitability, leverage, and liquidity. The asterisks used in Table 3-11 signify
whether the ratio is affected by debt-financing, working capital-financing, or both.
Two sets of financial ratio analysis are performed in this study for different levels in the
business hierarchy—the facility level and the business entity level. The business entity level is the
level above the facility level at which separate financial data is generated (e.g., corporate
divisions or subsidiaries). Both sets of analyses are based on survey data.
The survey provides a financial profile of the industry in 1985, 1988, and 1989 to
characterize the industry through several recent years. These years include a very poor year in
the pulp, paper, and paperboard industry (1985). and a healthy year for the industry (1989)—a
15 The Agency considered using the quick ratio in the financial analysis. The quick ratio is
similar to the current ratio, but excludes inventories from the calculation of current assets.
Current ratios are more commonly reported on financial summaries (S&P, 1992), and that
tradition is followed here.
3-47
-------
TABLE 3-11
FINANCIAL RATIOS INCLUDED IN THE PAPER, PULP, AND PAPERBOARD ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS
Financial
Ratio
Calculation
Profitability Ratios:
* Net Income Margin
* Return on Assets
Net Income/Sales Revenue
Net Income/Total Assets
Leverage Ratios:
• Times Interest Earned
+ • Debt Ratio
(EBIT + Depreciation)/lnterest Expense
Total Debt/Total Assets
Liquidity Ratios:
+ Current Ratio
+ Net Working Capital
+ Net Working Capital/Total Assets
Current Assets/Current Liabilities
Current Assets-Current Liabilities
(Current Assets-Current Liabilities)/ Total Assets
Notes: EBIT refers to earnings before interest and taxes.
Net Income refers to earnings after interest and taxes.
Owner's Equity refers to the difference between total assets and total liabilities.
Total Debt refers to total liabilities.
+ Indicates a ratio which could be directly affected by working capital approach to financing of
required pollution control investments.
* Indicates a ratio which could be directly affected by debt approach to financing of
required pollution control investments.
All ratios could be indirectly affected by either method of financing pollution control equipment.
ratios.wk3
24-Jun-93
3-48
-------
low point and a high point in the market cycle. (DeKing et al., 1990 and Mies et al., 1992
discuss the cyclical nature of the pulp, paper, and paperboard industry.) Thus the analysis will
characterize recent variations in financial structure in the context of normal, recent business
conditions. The cost annualization model and engineering cost data are incorporated in the
facilities'/firms' balance sheets under the alternative financing options. These two profiles
(before and after regulatory costs are incurred) are used to examine the potential effects of the
proposed regulations on the firms and facilities. In particular, the Agency searches for any
significant impacts that might exceed those seen in the industry's natural cycle.
3.22.2 Facility-Level Ratio Analysis
The ratio analysis is performed at the facility level to examine the potential regulatory
impacts on individual plants, particularly to flag and assess impacts less severe than closure.
Independent facilities, for whom the facility, business entity, and corporate levels are identical,
are examined only at the business entity level (see Section 3.2.2.3).
Some multifacility companies do not carry all financial components necessary for a
complete ratio analysis at the facility level. For example, for facilities that carry interest only at
the business entity or corporate level, a TIE ratio cannot be calculated. More than half of the
facilities do not carry noncurrent liabilities on the facility books, making it difficult to calculate a
meaningful return on equity. The return on sales or income margin can still be calculated. Since
many expenses are not carried at the facility level (e.g., income taxes, pension expenses, and
other corporate expenses), the ratio represents more of a gross income margin. The ratios
examined at the facility level are:
• Gross Income Margin. (Mill revenues - manufacturing costs - nonmanufacturing
costs)/ mill revenue. Depreciation expense is included in the nonmanufacturing
costs. For the incremental impacts, the annualized cost is also subtracted from
revenues.
• Return on Assets. Gross income, as calculated above, as a percentage of total
mill assets. The incremental impacts on this ratio were examined by decreasing
the gross income by the annualized cost, and increasing the asset base by the
capjtal investment required for each option.
3-49
-------
• Current Ratio. Current assets/current liabilities. The incremental impacts were
analyzed after the annualized cost for each option was taken out of current assets.
• Net Working Capital. Current assets - current liabilities. Incremental impacts
were examined by subtracting the annualized cost for each option.
• Net Working Capital/Total Assets. Net working capital, as calculated above, as a
percentage of total mill assets. For the incremental impacts, the net working
capital was adjusted for the annualized cost and the total assets were adjusted for
the new capital equipment needed under each option.
Net working capital and net working capital/total assets are included to examine both the
incremental impacts on liquidity (working capital as a proportion of mill assets), as well as the
mill's overall ability to finance the annual cost of regulation. Table 3-12 cross-references the
data in the survey with the components of the facility-level financial ratio analysis.
3.2.2.3 Business-Entity-Level Ratio Analysis
The ratio analysis performed at the business-entity level investigates the impacts of
aggregated costs on the company. If an entity operates five paper facilities, the ratio analysis
must incorporate the costs expected to be borne by all five facilities. In other words, while added
pollution control costs might not force any of the mills to close, the aggregate costs for several
mills might severely affect the company's financial health. The business entity is defined in the
survey as the level closest to the facility for which complete financial data are available.
Table 3-13 cross-references the survey data and the business-entity-level financial ratio analysis.
A ratio analysis is not planned at the corporate parent level, i.e., whatever owns the
business entity. Higher up the corporate hierarchy, the impacts become more diluted because of
an increased asset base. For single-establishment firms, ratio analysis at the facility level,
business-entity level, and the corporate level would coincide.
3-50
-------
TABLE 3-12
COMPONENTS NEEDED FOR FINANCIAL RATIOS
FACILITY-LEVEL ANALYSIS
Location of Data In 199O National Census
Part B: Financial and Economic Information
Independently Owned
1985 1988 1989
Multi-Facility Company
1985
1988
1989
Asset Related:
Current Assets
Total Assets
37c
38n
41 c
42n
45c
46n
49c
50m
53c
54m
57c
58m
Liability Related:
Current Liabilitie
Total Liabilities
39s 43e 47 a 51a 55a 59a
39a + 39b 43a + 43b 47a + 47b 51a + 51c 55a + 55c 59a + 59c
Income Statement Related:
Sales Revenues
Earnings Before Interest and Taxes (EBIT)
Interest Expense
Taxes
Manufacturing Costs
Non-Manufacturing Costs (w/depreciation)
Net Income
Depreciation
16a
16h
16i
16)
NN
NN
16k
16f
19a
19h
19i
19j
NN
NN
19k
19f
22a
22h
22i
22j
, NN
NN
22k
22f
65
NA
NA
NA
68
69a
65-168 + 69a)
69b
65
NA
NA
NA
71
72a
65-(71 +72a)
72b
65
NA
NA
NA
74
75a
65-(74 + 75a)
75b
Notes:NA Not available.
Income statement related data for facilities owned by multi-facility companies may not be accurate since
items such as taxes and interest may or may not be carried on the facility's books.
NN Not necessary. )
This information is not needed for the ratio analysis, since more accurate data can be obtained from
Section 2 of the questionnaire.
compnts.wkS 24-Jun-93
3-51
-------
TABLE 3-13
COMPONENTS NEEDED FOR FINANCIAL RATIOS
BUSINESS-ENTITY LEVEL ANALYSIS
Location of Data in 1 990 National Census
Part B: Financial and Economic Information
Independently Owned *
Component 1985 1988 1989
Asset Rotated:
Currant Assets See Table 3
Total Assets
Liability Related:
Current Liabilities
Total Liabilities
Income Statement Related:
Sales Revenues
Earnings Before Interest and Taxes (EBIT)
Interest Expense
Taxes
Net Income
Depreciation
Multi-Facility Company
1 985 1 988 1 989
15a 18a 21a
15d 18d 21d
15e 18e 21o
15h 18h 21h
16a 19a 22a
16h 19h 22h
16! 19i 22i
16j 19j 22j
16k 19k ' 22k
1 6f 1 9f 22f
Notes: * Components for independents are the same as the facility components found in Table 3-12.
s:\econ\pulp2\oia\sec_3\t3_13.wk3 24-Jun-93
3-52
-------
3.2.2,4 Baseline Results
Baseline results are based on the financial ratios and their change due to the business
cycle before the addition of incremental pollution control cost. After the ratios are calculated
for each facility and/or business entity, the average and median values are calculated. Table 3-14
presents the summary results for the facility-level ratio analysis for 1985, 1988, and 1989.l6 Both
the median and mean value are presented because of the variability in the ratios; median values
are much less sensitive to outliers. The median 1985 gross income margin and return on assets
values indicate how poor a year it was; these ratios are almost half the values for 1989. The
current ratio, on the other hand, remains above 1.0 for all 3 years, indicating that the typical
facility had more assets than liabilities. The industry downturn actually started at the end of
1989 (DeKing et al., 1990); most facilities closed out 1989 with lower net working capital than in
1988. This pattern is also seen in the drop in net working capital/total assets for 1989.
Baseline financial ratios for the company or business entity are shown in Table 3-15. As
expected, net income margin is smaller than the gross income margin seen in Table 3-14, but
with the same business cycle pattern. Return on assets also Is smaller for the company because
all costs are considered, and it also shows the business cycle pattern. Current ratio and debt to
asset ratio stayed very stable during this period, which might indicate that little can be learned
from these ratios in the impact analysis. The difference between the mean and median times
interest earned (TIE) is striking. Some companies have very small debts on their balance sheets
and therefore have very high TIE ratios, which skew the average upwards and away from the
median. A similar phenomenon occurs with the net working capital.
Tables 3-14 and 3-15 indicate the cyclical nature of the pulp, paper, and paperboard
industry. For this report, the fluctuations in financial ratios due to the business cycle are
"The first pass in the analysis revealed several outliers with large and negative values for
current assets.. Closer investigation revealed that ail outlying mills apportioned most of their
liabilities to an intercompany account that did not distinguish between current and noncurrent
liabilities. All of these intercompany liabilities were recorded as current. These large values
affected the current ratio and the net working capital estimates for the entire population. For
these mills, the intercompany account was excluded from the estimate of current liabilities. This
change did not affect the median net working capital.
3-53
-------
TABLE 3-14
BASELINE FACILITY-LEVEL RATIO ANALYSIS
ALL HILLS
Ratio
Gross Income Margin:
Mean:
Median:
Return on Assets:
Mean:
Median:
Current Ratio:
Mean:
Median:
Net Working Capita^:
Mean ($000):
Median ($000):
Net WC/ Total Assets:
Mean:
Median:
Baseline
1985
2.1%
5.7%
17.0%
9.5%
3.16
1.85
$5,275 $5
$2,211 $2
16.4%
11.0%
Paramel
1988
1.8%
11.6%
31.0%
17.3%
2.72
1.84
,948
:,778
12.0%
9.8%
:er
1989
0.3%
12.3%
32.3%
17.5%
3.26
1.81
$5,392
$2,284
10.3%
8.8%
Variation
87.9%
53.2%
47.6%
45.9%
16.4%
1.7%
11.3%
20.4%
37.2%
20.5%
Notes: This table includes independent, single-facility, and
multi-facility entities. There are 523 mills in the analysis.
D:\SMALLBUS\MRATIOS.WK3
28-Jun-93
3-54
-------
TABLE 3-15
BASELINE BUSINESS ENTITY-LEVEL RATIO ANALYSIS
ALL COMPANIES
Baseline Parameter
Ratio
Net Income Margfn:
Mean:
Median:
Return on Assets:
Mean:
Median:
Current Ratio:
Mean:
Median:
Net Working Capital:
Mean ($000):
Median ($000):
Net WC/ Total Assets:
Mean:
Median:
Debt/Asset Ratio
Mean:
Median:
Times Interest Earned:
Mean:
Median:
1985
1.8%
4.2%
4.6%
5.8%
3.55
1.90
$46,172
$5,584
20.3%
18.3%
51.5%
50.2%
45.5
6.3
1988
6.2%
5.3%
9.3%
8.5%
2.48
1.91
$70,231
$7,090
20.0%
17.5%
57.2%
53.2%
34.2
8.8
1989
4.7%
5.0%
8.0%
6.5%
2.43
1.79
$62,005
$5,841
18.2%
13.2%
58.4%
.54.4%
21.1
7.1
Percent
Variation
71.0%
19.8%
50.8%
31.8%
31.6%
6.0%
34.3%
21.2%
10.5%
28.3%
11.7%
7.8%
53.8%
28.8%
Notes: Includes independent, single-facility, and multi-facility entities.
There are 196 companies in the analysis.
D:\SMALLBUS\COMPANY\BIZSTAT2.WK3
28-Jun-93
3-55
-------
important to consider when assessing the impact of incremental pollution control costs. For all
ratios that do not involve net working capital, impacts will be evaluated on a facility-by-facility
basis, and the average and median impact will be reporte'd (i.e., the mean change). In contrast,
the incremental impacts for net working capital and net working capital/total assets were
measured on a population basis (i.e., the change in the mean). This is because some mills have
negative net working capital. Further reductions appear as positive changes and provide
misleading results.
3.23 Associated Impacts
3.2.3.1 Direct Impacts
The closure analysis is facility-specific and impacts associated with mill closure are based
on survey information. Direct, or primary, impacts such as job losses, revenue losses, and export
losses are all calculated based on specific mill closures. The direct impacts associated with a
specific regulatory alternative or option are estimated by summing the losses for all facilities
projected to close.
3.2.3.2 Secondary Impacts
Any positive or negative economic activity can have a ripple effect on the local and
regional economy. Whether it be the start-up of a factory, the introduction of a public spending
program, or reductions in export sales at a local manufacturing plant, changes in economic
activity influence the welfare of the surrounding region through inter-industrial relationships and
impacts on households. A factory closing, for example, would not only decrease sales of local
and regional raw material suppliers, but could also reduce the sales of local merchants through
lowered employment and earnings in the area.
The U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, has developed a
Regional Input-Output Modeling System (RIMS II) that aims to quantify these ripple effects for
3-56
-------
over 500 different industries in all regions of the nation (DOC, 1992). RIMS II is based on an
accounting framework called an input-output (I-O) table, which shows—for each industry—the
inputs purchased from and outputs sold to other industries and households in the region.
National-level I-O multipliers from RIMS II for SIC codes 261 (pulp mills), 262 (paper
mills), and 263 (paperboard mills) are used to estimate total impacts from projected mill
closures. Impacts estimated by these multipliers include both direct and indirect impacts, that is,
they include the impacts described in Section 3.2.3.1. The final-demand multiplier for output
(Table 3-16) represents the total dollar change in output for each dollar change in industry
output; e.g., every $1 change in pulp output results in a $3.52 change in total output. The final-
demand multiplier for employment is the total change in jobs for each $1,000,000 change in
output (Table 3-16). For example, a loss of $1,000,000 in paper shipments results in a loss of
27.2 jobs. This employment loss includes the loss in jobs estimated by the facility closure, i.e., it
includes both direct and indirect job losses. The multiplier is based on 1989 data, as is the
survey data (Pigler, 1993).
The financial model analysis estimates the loss in the value of shipments associated with
facility closures. The loss in the value of shipments estimated by the facility closures is the input
to the analysis of secondary and community effects.
3.2.3.3. Loss in Federal and State Tax Revenues
Tax shields that lower costs to the industry represent a loss in tax revenues to state and
federal governments. The difference between pre-tax and post-tax annualized costs represent the
potential loss in income to the governments.
3-57
-------
TABLE 3-16
RIMS II MULTIPLIERS FOR THE PULP, PAPER, AND PAPERBOARD INDUSTRIES
Industrial Category
Pulp Mills
Paper Mills
Paperboard Mills
Final-demand multipliers
Output
(dollars per dollar)
3.5183
3.2303
3.3589
Employment
(jobs per $1,000,000 )
29.7
27.2
28.2
Source: Pigler, 1993.
3-58
-------
3.3 MARKET IMPACT ANALYSIS METHODOLOGY
Implementing regulations to control air and water pollutants from pulp and paper
manufacturers will affect the costs of production in the U.S. pulp and paper industry. The costs
of the regulations will vary across the many different mills in the industry, depending on the
production processes currently employed. Mill-level production responses to these additional
costs will determine the market impacts of the regulations. Specifically, the cost of the
regulations may induce some mills, or product lines within mills, to close or to change their
current level of production. These choices affect, and in turn are affected by, the market price
for market pulp, paper, and paperboard products.
A variety of approaches may be used to quantify and evaluate economic impacts; they
reflect a variety of underlying paradigms. The market impact model applies standard
microeconomics concepts to model the supply of pulp, paper, and paperboard products and the
impacts of the regulations on production costs and facility output decisions. The three main
elements of the analysis are regulatory effects on the manufacturing facility, market responses,
and facility-market interactions. For a more comprehensive and technically detailed discussion of
the market impact analysis methodology and model, please see Appendix A of this report.
3.3.1 Market Impact Model Concepts
3.3.1.1 Facility-Level Effects
At any point in time, the costs that a firm faces can be classified as either unavoidable
(sunk) or avoidable. In the former category, we include costs to which the firm is committed and
that must be paid regardless of any future actions of the firm. The second category, avoidable
costs, describes any costs that are foregone by ceasing production. These costs can be further
refined to distinguish between costs that vary with the level of production and those that are
independent of the production level. For example, production factors such as labor, materials,
and capital (except in the short run) vary with the level of output, whereas expenditures for
3-59
-------
facility security and administration may be independent of production levels but avoidable if the
facility closes down.
Figure 3-6 illustrates the derivation of a facility supply function for a market pulp, paper,
or paperboard product from the classical U-shaped structure of production costs with respect to
output. The horizontal axis, q/t, represents output per period and the vertical axis, $/q,
represents the cost per unit of output. Let AVAC be the facility's average variable (avoidable)
cost curve and ATAC the average (avoidable) cost curve for producing the product. The vertical
distance between ATAC and AVAC is the per-unit average cost of nonvariable avoidable costs,
and it approaches zero as the number of units of output increases. MC is the marginal cost of
producing paper, paperboard, or market pulp, which intersects AVAC and ATAC at their
respective minimum points. All these curves are conditional on input prices and the technology
in place at the facility.
The facility supply function is the section of the marginal cost curve bounded by the
quantities qm and qM. qM is the largest feasible production rate that can be sustained at the
facility given the technology and other fixed factors in place, regardless of the output price.
Quantity qm is the minimum economically feasible production rate .determined by the minimum
of the AVAC curve, which coincides with the price p™. Suppose the market price of paper is less
than pm. In this case, the firm's best response is to close the facility and not produce paper
because P < AVAC implies that total revenue would be less than variable costs if the facility
operated at the associated output levels below qm.
Now consider the effect of the proposed regulatory control costs. These control costs fall
i
into one of two categories: avoidable variable and avoidable nonvariable. We characterized
these proposed costs as avoidable because a firm can choose to cease operation of the facility
and thus avoid incurring the costs of compliance. The variable control costs include the O&M
costs of the controls, and the nonvariable costs include compliance capital equipment.
The effect of these additional costs is illustrated in Figure 3-7. The facility's AVAC and
MC curves shift upward (to AVAC' and MC') by the per-unit variable compliance costs. In
addition, the nonvariable compliance costs increase total avoidable costs and thus the vertical
3-60
-------
$/q
pm .
Figure 3-6. Facility cost curves.
3-61
-------
MC'
MC
ATAC'
AVAC1
ATAC
AVAC
qm qm- qM
q/t
Figure 3-7. Effect of compliance costs on facility supply function.
3-62
-------
distance between AT AC' and AVAC'. The facility's supply curve shifts upward with marginal
costs, and the new (higher) minimum operating level (qm') is determined by a new (higher) pm/.
Now consider the effect of compliance costs on the derived demand for inputs at the
regulated facility. Paper and paperboard manufacturing facilities are market demanders of pulp.
We can employ a similar neoclassical analysis to the one above to demonstrate the effect of
compliance costs on the demand for the market pulp input. Figure 3-8 illustrates the paper and
paperboard manufacturing facility demand function for market pulp. Each point on the derived
demand curve equals the firm's maximum willingness to pay for the corresponding marginal
input. This is typically referred to as the input's value of marginal product (VMP), which is
equal to the price of the output (P) less the per-unit compliance costs (c) times the input's
"marginal physical product" (MPP), which is the incremental output attributable to the
incremental input. Ignoring any effect on the output price for now, an increase in per-unit •
compliance costs due to the regulations will lower the VMP of all inputs by the unit amount of
the additional compliance costs, leading to a downward shift in the derived demand curve in
section a of Figure 3-8 from Dy to D'y.
The paper and paperboard manufacturing facility demand curve for market pulp is
downward sloping in this example, indicating that the marginal physical product of market pulp
diminishes as more is used to produce paper and paperboard, and substitution possibilities exist
with other inputs. This model assumes that the input-output relationship between the market
pulp and the final paper and paperboard product is strictly fixed, not only by product
specification but also by constant efficiency of use at all input levels. Therefore, the VMP of the
market pulp is constant and the derived demand curve is horizontal with the constant VMP as
the vertical intercept, as shown in section b of Figure 3-8.
3.3.1.2 Market-Level Effects
Consider the relationship depicted in Figure 3-9 between the markets for a single paper
or paperboard product, Qx, and a market pulp input, Qy. Qy, along with other inputs, such as
labor, energy, and chemicals, is used in the production of Qv We assume that prices for the
3-63
-------
$/q.
qy/t
a) Without Fixed Input Coefficients
•V
qy/t
b) With Fixed Input Coefficients
Figure 3-8. Effect of compliance costs on derived demand for market pulp at regulated facility.
3-64
-------
$/Qx
Px1
PxO
$/Qy
Py2
Py3 =
P/1
Qxi Qxo
(a) Market for Paper or Paperboard Product, Qx
Dx
Qx/t
Qy1 Q/3 Qy2 QyO
(b) Market for Pulp, Qy
Figure 3-9. Market equilibria with and without compliance costs.
Qy/t
3-65
-------
respective commodities are determined in competitive markets (i.e., individual facilities have
negligible power over the market price of the commodities and thus take the price as "given" by
the market). Under perfect competition, market prices and quantities are determined by the
intersection of market supply and demand curves. A market supply curve is the sum of all
facility supply curves, and a market demand curve is the sum of the demand curves for all
demanders of the commodity. The demanders of paper or paperboard product, Qx, are final
product consumers, and the demanders of market pulp, Qy, are the individual facilities that
purchase market pulp for producing paper and paperboard products. Without the proposed
compliance costs, the market quantity and price of paper or paperboard product, Qx (Q^, P^),
are determined by the intersection of the market demand curve (DJ and the market supply curve
(SJ, and the market quantity and price of market pulp, Qy (Q^, Py,,), are determined by the
intersection of the market demand curve (Dy) and market supply curve (Sy).
Imposing the regulations increases the costs of producing pulp and, thus, paper and
paperboard, shifting the market supply function for both commodities upward to S'x and S'y,
respectively. The supply shift in the market for paper and paperboard products causes the
market quantity of each to fall to Qxl and the market price to rise to Pxi in the new equilibrium.
In the market for pulp, the drop in the market quantity is unambiguous; however, the direction
of the change in the market price can only be determined if we know the relative magnitudes of
the demand and supply shifts. If the downward demand effect dominates, the price will fall (e.g.,
Pyl); if the upward supply effect dominates, the price will rise (e.g., P^); and if the effects just
offset each other, the price remains unchanged (e.g., Py3 = P^).
The sign (positive or negative) of the effect of these market adjustments on commodity
prices and quantities is summarized in Figure 3-10; the magnitude of these effects is estimated by
the market impact model. The supply shifts for market pulp, paper, and paperboard cause the
market price to rise and market quantity to fall for these commodities at the new equilibrium.
However, the downward shift in the demand curve for market pulp will have an offsetting effect
on price, leaving the total effect ambiguous, while exacerbating the effect on quantity, resulting in
an even lower quantity produced. In both cases, the producers that are unaffected by the
regulations receive the higher price for their products without the associated increase in
compliance costs and thus increase their production levels.
3-66
-------
Quantity
Increase Decrease
Increase
Price
Decrease
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
a) Market Pulp
Quantity
Increase Decrease
Increase
Price
Decrease
No
Yes
Yes
No
b) Paper and Paperboard Products
Figure 3-10. Market adjustments for market pulp, paper, and paperboard products.
3-67
-------
3.3.1.3 Facility-Level Response to Control Costs and New Market Prices
In evaluating the market effects for pulp, paper, and paperboard products, we must
distinguish between the initial effect of the regulations and the net effect after all markets have
adjusted. Initially all affected facilities' supply curves for market pulp, paper, and paperboard
shift upward by the unit variable costs of the regulation. As a result, all affected facilities'
derived demand curves for market pulp shift downward by the unit variable control costs.
However, the upward shift in the industry supply curves for paper and paperboard pushes up the
prices of those commodities, which subsequently raises the VMP of the market pulp and, thus,
puts upward pressure on the derived demand for that commodity. In general, the initial upward
shift in supply at the facility will be greater than the subsequent increase in market price so that
the mill reduces supply of market pulp, paper, or paperboard. The initial downward shift in
demand will typically dominate the subsequent upward shift so that the net shift is downward and
the mill reduces demand for market pulp. However, determining which shift dominates for a
particular mill is difficult: it depends on the relative magnitude of the facility-specific unit
variable costs of the regulation and the changes in market prices.
Given changes in market prices and costs, mills will elect to either:
Continue to operate, adjusting production and input use based on new revenues
and costs, or
Close the facility if expected revenues do not exceed total avoidable costs.
This decision can be extended to the multiproduct facility where product lines may be closed if
product revenues are less than product-specific avoidable costs, and the entire facility may be
closed if total expected revenues from all products (market pulp, paper, and paperboard) do not
exceed facility-specific avoidable costs.
This approach to modeling the facility closure decision is based on conventional
microeconomic theory. It compares the AT AC—which includes all cost components that fall to
zero when production discontinues—to the expected postregulatory price. Figure 3-7 illustrates
3-68
-------
this comparison. If price falls below the AT AC, total revenue would be less than the total
avoidable costs. In this situation, the owner's cost-minimizing response is to cease production.
An additional aspect of the facility-level impacts is the quantity adjustments. Changes in
costs will change producers' output rates. However, some of this effect is mitigated when prices
are increased. Of course, facility and product-line closures directly translate into quantity
reductions. However, the output of operating facilities also will change as will supply from
foreign sources. Affected facilities that continue to produce may increase or decrease their
output levels depending on the relative magnitude of the unit variable control costs and the
changes in market prices. Unaffected facilities will not face an upward shift in their product
supply curves, so their response to higher product prices is to increase production. This response
is illustrated in Figure 3-11 as an upward movement along the facility's supply curve for the
product. Foreign producers, which do not incur higher production costs because of the
regulations, will respond in the same manner as these unaffected U.S. mills.
33.2 Operationalizing the Market Impact Model
To estimate'the economic impacts of the regulations, we operationalized the competitive
market model of the pulp and paper industry outlined in the previous subsections. The model
incorporates the facility-specific information on production obtained from the EPA's 1990
National Census of Pulp, Paper, and Paperboard Manufacturing Facilities (EPA, 1991) and model
I
parameters characterizing domestic and foreign (export) demands as well as foreign supply
(imports). The model incorporates these data sources to provide an empirical characterization of
the U.S. pulp and paper industry and product markets for a base year of 1989. We chose this
base year of analysis because it is the last year for which facility-specific production and technical
data were available from the National Census (EPA, 1991) and for which supporting economic
data were readily available.
The model analyzes market adjustments for 31 paper and paperboard product markets
and 6 market pulps by employing a process of latonnemenl whereby prices approach equilibrium
through successive correction—modeled as a Walrasian auctioneer. Integrated facilities and
3-69
-------
$/q
o
pm
•m
,M
Qi/t
Figure 3-11. Movement along the product supply function.
5-70
-------
paper-making facilities constitute those facilities supplying final paper products; the pulp mills
and those integrated mills involved in the market for pulp, either as a supplier or demander,
constitute those facilities included in the model for market pulps. The model also includes a
foreign trade sector with which to assess the impact of international trade responses on market
outcomes and vice versa.
To implement this model, we identified commodities and facilities to be included in the
analysis, specified the supply and demand side of the market and associated response parameters,
I
specified the foreign trade sector and provided the corresponding response parameters,
incorporated demand and supply specifications into a market model framework, and evaluated
market adjustments due to imposing regulatory compliance costs and estimated the impacts.
3.33.1 Model Dimensions
Clearly the analysis must account for all marketable commodities involved in producing
pulp and paper, as well as all suppliers of these commodities. Figure 3-12 illustrates the modeled
interactions between commodities and producers. Trje first marketable product is pulp, either
bleached or unbleached; the second marketable product is the final paper or paperboard product.
The model analyzes the market adjustments for 6 market pulps and 31 paper and paperboard
products. All of these products are consumed and produced domestically, as well as traded
internationally. Therefore, domestic producers export some pulp and paper products to other
countries, and foreign producers supply their products to U.S. markets.
The pulp and paper industry is characterized by both nonintegrated and vertically
integrated mills. Nonintegrated mills include pulp mills that produce market pulp as well as
paper mills that purchase market pulp to produce paper and paperboard products. Vertically
integrated mills rely mostly on their own production of pulp to produce paper and paperboard
products. Those vertically integrated mills without enough internally produced pulp are also
demanders of market pulp, and those that produce an excess supply of pulp are suppliers of
market pulp. We modeled the production from 566 pulp, paper, and paperboard manufacturing
facilities, including 28 pulp mills, 303 paper mills, and 235 integrated mills.
3-71
-------
Domestic
Consumers
Foreign
(Exports)
C
PAPER/PAPERBOARD (31)
Integrated
Mills
(235)
i
Paper Mills
(303)
Foreign
(Imports)
Foreign
(Exports)
MARKET PULP (6)
Pulp Mills
(28)
Foreign
(Imports)
Figure 3-12. Interactions between commodities and producers.
3-72
-------
3.3.2.2 Commodities
EPA's 1990 National Census of Pulp, Paper, and Paperboard Manufacturing Facilities
identifies the 566 mills existing in 1989 that may be affected, either directly or indirectly, by the
air and water pollution regulations. The detailed production data obtained from this source on
each mill form the basis for characterizing the commbdities included in the model. Table 3-17
lists the products with a description of each product and its product code.
The National Census identifies 42 product markets to analyze—33 final paper and
paperboard products and 9 pulp produpts. However, National Census data on facility-level
production indicate no U.S. production of either "other shipping sack" (product code 32) or
"hardboard" (product code 52) in 1989. Therefore, the markets for these two product groups are
not included in the model.
Although some of the pulp product categories provided by the National Census
distinguish between bleached and unbleached pulps, not all pulp categories have this distinction.
Consequently, as shown in Table 3-18, the pulp product categories were expanded to 17 to
account for bleached and unbleached versions of each pulp by matching the pulp category with
pulp process codes from the National Census. Bleached and unbleached pulps were categorized
using National Census data on the fiber source indicated by the pulp process codes and the
percentage of the fiber that is bleached and unbleached. Distinguishing the pulp products by
these features—pulping process and bleaching—is particularly important because the regulations
arc aimed primarily at chemical pulping and bleaching. Thus, the model includes 17 pulp inputs
into the production of paper and paperboard.
Some subsets of the 17 pulps described above are sold on the market (i.e., market pulps).
A number of the pulp inputs are only produced at integrated facilities for in-house production of
paper and papcrboard products and arc consequently not marketed. In addition, some of these
pulps are traded in very small quantities by a small number of suppliers; therefore, data were
insufficient to derive prices for some of" these market pulp products. The U.S. Department of
Commerce's Current Industrial Reports: Pulp, Paper, and Board does not contain data on value of
3-73
-------
TABLE 3-17
PULP, PAPER, AND PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS
Product (Code)"
Product Description
Pulp
Special alpha and dissolving
woodpulp (1)
Sulfate-bleached (2)
Sulfate-unbleached (3)
Sulfite-bleached (4)
Sulfite-unbleached (5)
Groundwood-bleached (6)
Groundwood-unbleached (7)
Thermomechanical-bleached (8)
Thermomechanical-unbleached (9)
Semichemical-bleached (10)
Semichemical-unbleached (11)
Defibrated or exploded-bleached
(12)
Defibrated or exploded-unbleached
(13)
Secondary-bleached (14)
Secondary-unbleached (15)
Cotton and rag pulp-bleached and
unbleached (16)
Chemical pulp from wood and other fibers with a very
high alpha cellulose content, readily adaptable for uses
other than paper and paperboard making.
Made from an alkaline pulp manufacturing process that
cooks chips in a pressure vessel using a liquor of primarily
sodium sulfide and sodium hydroxide with sodium sulfate
and lime being used to replenish these chemicals in
recovery operations (also kraft).
Made from acid pulp manufacturing process that cooks
chips in a pressure vessel using a liquor composed of
calcium, sodium, magnesium, or ammonia salts of
sulfurous acid.
Slurry produced by mechanically abrading fibers from
barked logs through forced contact with the surface of a
revolving grindstone. Used as newsprint and publication
paper.
Pulp made by presteaming chips and reducing them into
their fiber components during an initial mechanical
treatment in refiners under elevated temperature and
pressure. Subsequent refining done at atmospheric
pressure.
Lower quality pulp made by cooking fibrous materials in a
neutral sodium sulfite-sodium carbonate liquor followed
by a final separation of the fiber using unpressurized
mechanical means.
Pulp made by thermomechanical process in which
woodchips are pretreated with a chemical, usually sodium
sulfite, either prior to or during presteaming as an aid to
subsequent mechanical processing in refiners.
Any type of paper- and paperboard-making fiber obtained
from wastepapers and other used, reclaimable fiber
sources.
Pulp made from rags or cotton linters by a conventional
cooking process with lime and sodium hydroxide, followed
by refining and bleaching.
3-74
-------
TABLE 3-17 (cont)
Product (Code)*
Product Description
All other fiber, n.e.c. (17)
Pulps other than wood such as pulp of fibrous vegetable
material (e.g., straw, reed, bagasse, bamboo, etc.); or
synthetic and semi-synthetic sources (e.g., glass, fiberglass,
rayon, nylon, combinations).
Paper
Newsprint (20)
Uncoated groundwood paper (21)
Clay-coated printing and converted
paper (22)
Uncoated free sheet (23)
Bleached bristols (24)
Cotton fiber writing paper and thin
paper (25)
Unbleached kraft packaging and
industrial converting paper (26)
Special industrial paper, except
specialty packaging (27)
Tissue (28)
Wrapping (30)
Light, inexpensive grade made largely from mechanical
pulps and some unbleached sulfite or other chemical
pulps.
A higher grade than newsprint that is smoother and
brighter and used in newspaper inserts, catalogs,
paperback books, and directories.
Printing and converting papers that contain a layer of
coating material, such as clay or pigment, in combination
with an adhesive.
Contains no more than 10% mechanical pulps, including
most grades of business paper (forms, bond, stationary,
tablet, envelope, xerox, and computer paper, and cover
and text grades used in printing).
High-quality cardboards used for products such as index
tags, cards, file folders, and postcards.
Papers in which cotton or other nonwood fibers comprise
25% or more of the total (e.g., bond, ledget, specialty
papers [also, rag]).
Various types of paper used for industrial or commercial
purposes, such as wrapping papers, bag and sack stock,
specialty papers.
Special industrial papers such as photographic sensitizing
paper, blotting paper, filter paper.
Light, fairly transparent, strong, absorbable, easily
disposable paper, characterized by its gauze-like texture,
made from mainly bleached kraft and sulfite pulps. Used
for sanitary products.
Grade of nonsanitary tissue, all M.G. and M.F. wrapping
papers,,treated and untreated butcher papers, arid
miscellaneous wrapping.
3-75
-------
TABLE 3-17 (cent)
Product (Code)*
Product Description
Shipping sack (31)
Other shipping sack (32)
Other bag and sack (33)
Other bag and sack paper for
conversion (34)
Waxing stock (35)
Other (36)
Specialty packaging (37)
Glassine, greaseproof, and vegetable
parchment (38)
Paperboard
Unbleached kraft (40)
Semichemical paperboard (41)
Recycled paperboard (42)
Wet machine board (43)
Paper made mainly from sulfate or soda, unbleached or
bleached woodpulp characterized by toughness and
strength, used in the manufacture of shipping sacks.
Rope and combination kraft and rope shipping sack
paper.
All other kraft wrapping paper made, mainly from sulfate
or soda, used, in the manufacture of grocery bags and bags
other than shipping sacks.
Used for conversion in liquor, millinery, notion, or other
variety bags.
Packaging paper with weight over 29.4 g/m2.
Other packaging and industrial converting paper such as
asphalting and creping stocks, coating and laminating,
gummed, twisting and spinning stocks (weight over 29.4
g/m2).
Packaging paper of weight not more than 150g/m2.
Papers made from pure chemical woodpulp or from
mixtures of chemical woodpulp, cotton fiber pulp, treated
by highly hyclrated or hand beaten to render the resulting
paper resistant to oil, grease, and water.
High-strength paperboard made from sulfate pulp, usually
with a naturally brown color from unbleached pulp.
Made from semichemical pulp, mostly used for
corrugating medium, which forms the inner, fluted layer
of cardboard and corrugated containers.
Made from a combination of recycled fibers from various
grades of paper stock, used for folding boxboard; core,
can, and tube grades, corrugating medium; and gypsum
linerboard.
Paperboard manufactured using a paper machine
consisting essentially of a wire-covered cylinder rotating in
a vat of pulpstock on which a mat of varying thickness is
formed by drainage, such as binder's board and shoe
board.
3-76
-------
TABLE 3-17 (cont.)
Product (Code)*
Product Description
Construction paper (50)
Hardboard (51)
Insulating board (52)
Heavy paper used for watercolor and crayon artwork,
made in various colors primarily from groundwood pulp.
Paperboard made resistant to water and ink penetration
by exposure to high degree of sizing treatments.
Paperboard used for insulating electric cables.
Bleached linerboard (60)
Folding carton type board (61)
Milk carton board (62)
Heavyweight cup and round nested
food container (63)
Plate, dish, and tray stock (64)
Bleached paperboard for
miscellaneous packaging (65)
Other solid bleached board (66)
Molded pulp products (70)
.Kraft paperboard used to line or face corrugated
coreboard to form shipping boxes and various other
containers.
Type of boxboard made of bleached chemical woodpulp
and used in the manufacture of "folding type" containers
that are formed, filled, and closed by the user.
Special grade of bleached boxboard capable of being
converted into containers for milk, cream, and other
beverages.
Bleached paperboard used in the manufacture of cups
and other nested cylindrical containers, used for hot and
cold drinks and in packaging moist, liquid, and oily foods.
Bleached paperboard, hard-sized for moisture resistance
and strength qualities.
Paperboard for miscellaneous packaging purposes such as
nonfolding board for shipping cases and set-up boxboard.
Single-ply, homogeneous types of paperboards, made from
the same stock throughout the sheet structure, including
paperboard for moist, oily, and liquid foods.
Products including fruit and vegetable packs and egg
cartons.
"For all products termed bleached or unbleached: bleaching is the process of chemically
treating fibers to reduce or remove coloring matter so that the pulp is improved in terms of
whiteness or brightness; unbleached is produced without being treated with bleaching agents'.
3-77
-------
TABLE 3-18
PULP PRODUCTS, PRODUCT CODES, AND PROCESS CODES
Pulp Product
Special alpha and dissolving woodpulp
Sulfate-bleached
Sulfate-unbleached
Sulfite-bleached
Sul fite-unbleached
Groundwood-bleached
Groundwood-unbleached
Thermomechanical-bleached
Thermomechanical-unbleached
Semichemical-bleached
Semichemical-unbleached
Defibrated or exploded-bleached
Defibrated or exploded-unbleached
Secondary-bleached
Secondary-unbleached
Cotton and rag pulp-bleached and
unbleached
All other fiber, n.e.c.
Pulp Product
Code
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
National Census
Code'
A,D
C, W
C,W
B
B
H, J
H,J
G
G
E
E
I,F
'l,F
K, L, M, N, O, P,
U,Y,Z
K, L, M, N, 0, P,
U,Y,Z
V
Q,X,SS
Process
F S T,
R, S, T,
"Process codes taken from Subappendix Table AA-1.
3-78
-------
product shipments and quantity of product shipped for a number of pulps because of disclosure
concerns. Thus, the model analyzes only six market pulps for which good information was
available:
• Special alpha and dissolving woodpulp
• Bleached sulfate
• Unbleached sulfate
• Bleached sulfite
• Bleached secondary fiber
• Unbleached secondary fiber
3.32.3 Domestic Supply of Pulp, Paper, and Paperboard
In this model, facilities are classified as either integrated or nonintegrated, and
nonintegrated mills are broken down further into pulp mills and paper mills. Each type of
facility has a different decision to make regarding production of pulp, paper, and paperboard, so
we model the production decisions at each type of facility accordingly.
Integrated mills must determine optimal output given the market prices for all paper
products they produce, which will determine the amount of internal pulp to produce. Excess
supply of pulp will spillover into the market, while excess demand will cause the facility to
demand market pulp. For nonintegrated paper mills,-the market prices for pulp inputs and final
paper and paperboard outputs will determine the optimal level of output to produce, and then,
the corresponding market pulp to purchase. For pulp mills, the price of market pulp will
determine the optimal supply of market pulp. The market supply of pulp is the sum of supply
from all market pulp suppliers, and the market demand for pulp is the sum of demand from all
market pulp demanders. The same is true for paper and paperboard products.
3-79
-------
Mills have the ability to vary output in the face of production cost changes. To allow for
mills to vary output in the face of regulatory control costs, the model uses facility-specific,
upward-sloping supply curves for each product. The model employs supply functions for pulp
and paper products that are derived from a generalized Leontief technology with the assumption
of no substitutability across final products (i.e., cross-price elasticity of supply equal to zero for
all mill outputs). The specification also restricts production to a fixed-proportion relationship
between paper and pulp—that is, each unit of paper product requires a fixed number of units of
pulp input. This fixed-proportions relationship implies that the firm's profit function, supply
functions, and derived demand functions depend on product output price and market pulp input
prices only insofar as they depend on net price. Further, we assumed that the variable
proportions input combines with pulp according to a generalized Leontief technology, which is
not fixed proportion.
The upward-sloping product supply curve for each facility is econometrically estimated by
ordinary least squares (OLS) using facility-specific data on production from the 1990 National
Census of Pulp, Paper, and Paperboard Manufacturing Facilities and market prices obtained from
U.S. Department of Commerce data. The supply curves are specified over a productive range
with an upper bound given by facility production capacity and a lower bound given by the
facility's minimum economically viable output level.
3.32.4 Incorporating Regulatory Control Costs
The starting point for assessing the impact of the regulations on the markets for pulp and
paper products is to incorporate the mill-level regulatory compliance costs. The compliance costs
for each mill are estimated by Agency engineers and include the total capital investment, the
annual general and administrative costs, and the annual operating and maintenance costs
(variable costs).
The primary challenge of incorporating regulatory control costs into the model structure
is to appropriately assign variable production costs to the pulp products directly affected by the
incidence of control costs. In some cases this assignment is straightforward, such as the case of
3-80
-------
bleach plant process changes or the case of bleach plant process vent controls. In these cases,
the variable costs are shared by each bleached pulp product produced by the affected process.
Other cases are not as straightforward, such as the case of secondary wastewater treatment
controls. Because the costs of these controls are not readily attributable to any specific
production area of the mill, the costs are assumed to be shared by all pulp products produced at
i
the mill. The result of assigning variable costs to the pulp products produced by each mill is a
mill-specific, per-unit production cost change for each of the 17 pulp products.
The second challenge of incorporating regulatory control costs into the model structure is
i
to calculate the annual nonvariable cost of regulation-imposed controls. The annual nonvariable
control costs are determined from the net present discounted value (NPDV) of the stream of
annual cash outflows, where the cash outflows are the total capital investment and the annual
general and administrative costs. The length of the stream of cash outflows corresponds to the
average depreciable life of the capital investment, which is estimated as 15 years, and the costs
are discounted using the facility-specific discount rate reported in the National Census (which
averages around 12 percent). The annual nonvariable control cost is then computed by
annualizing the NPDV over the lifetime of the investment at the facility-specific rate of discount.
The annual nonvariable control costs enter the model at the facility level, while the per-unit
variable control costs enter at the product level for all facilities affected by the regulations.
3.32.5 The Facility's Product-Level Supply Decisions
The production decisions at the three types of facilities—integrated paper mills,
nonintegrated paper mills, and pulp mills—are affected differently by the variable costs of control
(i.e., the annual O&M costs). These direct costs are borne by pulp producers, both suppliers of
pulp to the market and to integrated mills that produce and consume their own pulp. Because
of the direct costs of control, market pulp prices will rise, leading to indirect costs borne by
nonintegrated paper mills and integrated paper mills who purchase market pulp. The
nonvariable control costs do not directly affect product-level supply decisions except in the case
of facility closure, where supply is reduced to zero.
3-81
-------
For integrated mills, the variable costs of control associated with onsite production of
pulp will be borne at the level of paper and paperboard production. These costs are expressed
per unit of pulp and can be transmitted up to the paper product through the input ratios.
Integrated mills will be indirectly affected by increases in the price of market pulp inputs. These
i
increases in pulp prices are transmitted through the purchased input ratios. Nonintegrated paper
mills may not be directly affected by the control costs, but they will be indirectly affected through
the changes in the prices of market pulp inputs to paper production. Pulp mills will be directly
affected by the regulatory control costs, which enter the supply decision as a net price change to
pulp producers.
3.33.6 Facility Closure Decisions
The facility may not always find complying with the regulation feasible and thus may shut
down the pulp and paper manufacturing operation because it is no longer profitable. Thus, a
facility's optimal choice could be to produce zero output (i.e., close the facility). The model
defines the sufficient condition for production at the mill as non-negative net earnings before
interest, depreciation, and taxes (EBEDT). EBIDT is defined as the annual difference between
postregulatory production revenues less postregulatory production costs, including the variable
and nonvariable costs of compliance. The closure decision as defined here does not include an
annualized value for the liquidation opportunity cost, which is equivalent to assuming that the
opportunity cost is offset by the costs of closing the facility.
3.32.7 Domestic Demand For Pulp And Paper Products
Market Pulp. The market impact model does not specify an exogenous demand function
for market pulps because that demand is derived from the paper supply decisions at the
integrated and paper mills. Therefore, once the paper and paperboard production decisions at
each mill have been made, the mill-specific, purchased input ratios for each market pulp will
determine the domestic demand for each market pulp. Internal consumption of pulp is
determined by mill-specific, onsite input ratios for each pulp input. These on-site input ratios
3-82
-------
also form the basis for transmitting the variable compliance costs expressed per unit of pulp
produced at the mill to per-unit variable compliance costs at the level of paper and paperboard
products. We derived the mill-specific, purchased input ratios for each market pulp and the mill-
specific, onsite ratios for each pulp input from technical production data reported in the National
Census. We assumed these ratios to be constant throughout the analysis, thereby restricting each
mill to produce paper and paperboard products with the same combination of fiber sources, in
the same relative amounts, both before and after imposing the regulations.
The model assumes the integrated mills that met all pulp input needs through onsite
production in 1989 will not be active on the markets for pulp and will continue to satisfy all pulp
requirements internally after imposing the regulation. Thus, these mills are neither suppliers nor
demanders in the markets for pulp. However, the model does account for the interaction of
those integrated facilities that were active in the pulp markets during 1989, by specifying supply
relationships for market pulp suppliers, or by specifying purchased pulp input ratios for market
pulp demanders.
Paper and Paperboard Products. The market impact model uses an exogenous demand
function for paper and paperboard products. The function is consistent with a constant elasticity
demand curve. The function was econometrically estimated, producing an elasticity of demand.
The demand elasticity measures the proportional change in quantity demanded given a
proportional change in price. Economic theory suggests that the elasticity is negative (i.e., a rise
in price should induce a: reduction in quantity demanded, all else equal). The absolute value of a
product's demand elasticity measure is often compared to a benchmark value of 1. An absolute
value greater (less) than 1 indicates that demand is elastic (inelastic) with respect to price.
3.3.2.8 Modeling the Foreign Sector
The importance of including a foreign sector in the economic model is highlighted by the
significant level of international trade of products manufactured by facilities in the U.S. pulp and
paper industry. Section Two of this report provides detailed information on the extent of foreign
3-83
-------
supply of pulp and paper products to the U.S. (imports) and foreign demand for U.S.-produced
pulp and paper products (exports).
The market model specifies general functions for the foreign supply and demand for each
market pulp, paper, and paperboard product. These functions incorporate estimates of the
elasticities of foreign supply and foreign demand, which determine the responsiveness of foreign
trade flows to changes in domestic product prices. These elasticities were numerically computed,
rather than econometrically estimated, because domestic elasticity estimates are believed to
understate the price responsiveness of trade flows. Where foreign trade is a relatively minor
component of U.S. consumption or production, elasticities imply that regulation-induced price
changes may generate large proportional changes in imports and exports. But these changes may
not be so large in absolute value, given the small initial values of foreign trade. Price-taking in
world markets should dampen the price effects of regulation in U.S. markets because
theoretically large potential import supplies are available at the "world" price, and U.S. producers
are not able to significantly raise the price of exports on world markets.
3.3.3 Determining Market Equilibria
The market impact model evaluates the supply and demand in each pulp, paper, and
paperboard product market. Recall that the market supply of pulp is the sum of supply from
U.S. mills plus foreign supply. In similar fashion, the market supply of paper and paperboard
products is the sum of supply from all paper and paperboard producers, including foreign
suppliers. Recall also that the market demand for pulp is the sum of derived demand for market
pulp across all U.S. mills plus foreign demand. In similar fashion, the market demand of paper
and paperboard products is the sum of demand from all paper and paperboard consumers,
including foreign demand.
In the market impact model, each type of facility, integrated or nonintegrated, makes a
supply decision. The model is set into motion when facilities face increased production costs due
to compliance, which cause the facility-specific production responses. The cumulative effect of
these responses leads to a change in the market price that all producers (affected and
3-84
-------
unaffected) and consumers face, which leads to further responses by producers (affected and
unaffected) as well as consumers and thus new market prices, and so on. The new
postregulatory equilibria is the result of a series of iterations between producer and consumer
responses and market adjustments, until a stable market price arises where total market supply
equals total market demand.
The process for determining equilibrium prices (and outputs) is modeled as a Walrasian
auctioneer. The auctioneer calls out a price for each product and evaluates the reactions by all
participants (producers and consumers, both foreign and domestic), comparing quantities
supplied and demanded to determine the next price that will guide the market closer to
equilibrium (i.e., market supply equal to market demand). The model employs an algorithm to
simulate the auctioneer process and find a new equilibrium price and quantity for all 37 pulp and
paper product markets simultaneously. The model is governed by decision rules that ensure the
auctioneer process will converge to an equilibrium. The result of this approach is a vector of
post-compliance product prices that equilibrates supply and demand for all product markets.
3.3.4 Postregulatory Impact Estimates
The market model equilibria results can be summarized as both market-level and facility-
level impacts. Market-level results include adjustments in product prices, market-level
production quantity changes, changes in international trade flows, and changes in aggregate
economic welfare as measured by changes in consumer and producer surpluses.
Facility-level impacts include an evaluation of the pre-tax postregulatory compliance cost,
product-line and facility closures, and changes in production, production costs, and EBIDT. In
addition, the model computes changes in employment attributable to the changes in output at
each mill. These output changes are due to product-line and facility closures as well as
adjustments in production at mills that continue to operate under regulation. Workers'
dislocation costs associated with industry-wide job losses are also calculated based on the one-
time willingness to pay to avoid an involuntary unemployment episode.
3-85
-------
3.4 RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN FINANCIAL/ AND MARKET IMPACT ANALYSIS
METHODOLOGIES
The financial and market models provide related investigations of the potential impacts of
increased pollution control costs. The financial model, clearly the more conservative of the two
approaches, incorporates the following conservative assumptions and approaches:
• No cost pass-through. The mill is not allowed to raise prices to recoup increased
pollution control costs. This is tantamount to assuming an inexhaustible supply of
imports to keep domestic prices from rising.
• No growth. The mills are assumed to be operating at or near capacity. No
growth can occur without the costs of expansion.
• Net income, rather than cash flow, to estimate earnings.
• Comparison of the net present value of future earnings against the salvage value
to determine closure.
• Calculations of impacts only for those mills expected to incur pollution control
costs.
The financial model focuses only on the facility. Results from the financial model predict mill
closures and show how such closures will affect employment, revenue, and exports.
In contrast, the market approach uses an econometric model to estimate the impacts of
additional pollution control costs on the pulp, paper, and paperboard industry. The market
model can be distinguished from the financial model based on the following:
• Facilities may incorporate price increases to cover added pollution control costs.
• A mill may adjust output along product lines to maximize profits.
» Nonpulp, paper, or paperboard revenues are included in earnings estimates.
t
• Cash flow is used as a measure of earnings.
• A mill is closed only if revenues do not exceed total avoidable costs (i.e., the
salvage value of the mill is not estimated).
3-86
-------
• All mills in the industry are included in the market model.
» Imports affect market-level price and quantity changes.
Based on these differences, a mill is more likely to remain open in the market model, and the
market model could show impacts for mills estimated to bear no costs for pollution control. (For
example, a paper producer might not be able to sustain production if the price of input pulp
increases while the prices for the final product do not.) The price increases calculated in the
market model cannot be incorporated in the financial model because they are based on mill
closures and product line shifts that occur as the model moves toward equilibrium. Employment
impacts are estimated from mill closures and output changes in the market model.
The results of the financial model and market model, then, will differ. The financial
model is likely to show consistently greater impacts from the regulations than the market model
and possibly a different set of closure mills. Each approach has its own strengths and
weaknesses. Using both models, however, yields the full range of possible impacts associated
with the rulemaking.
3.5 REGULATORY FLEXIBILITY ANALYSIS METHODOLOGY
The Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA) came into effect on January 1, 1981 (EPA, 1992b).
A goal of the act is to establish a mechanism to provide policymakers with information on how
regulatory options1 affect small entities. The intent is to ensure that the chosen regulatory
alternative does not have undue or disproportionate impacts on small entities. The Agency has
developed guidelines for implementing the Regulatory Flexibility Act (EPA, 1992b).
3.5.1 Definition of Small Entity
RFA Section 601 states "For the purpose of this chapter...(3) the term 'small business'
has the same meaning as the term 'small business concern' under section 3 of the Small Business
Act, unless an agency, after consultation with the Office of Advocacy of the Small Business
3-87
-------
Administration and after opportunity for public comment, establishes one or more definitions of
such terms what are appropriate to the activities of the agency " (EPA, 1992b, Appendix A).
The U.S. Small Business Administration issues definitions of "small businesses" in Code of
Federal Regulations, Title 13, Part 121. For pulp, paper, and paperboard mills (SIC codes 2611,
2621, and 2631, respectively), the standard is 750 employees. A small entity, therefore, is defined
as a business entity with less than 750 employees.
3.5.2 Alternate Definitions of Small Entity
RFA Section 601 allows an agency to establish alternative definitions for a small entity.
The rulemaking focuses on individual facility performance with respect to meeting increased
pollution control requirements. For this reason, two sets of definitions are developed—one on a
company basis (for consistency with the Small Business Administration definition), and one on a
facility basis (in keeping with the basis for the ruleraaking).
For two reasons, the basis for the alternate definitions is the number of employees, both
production and nonproduction.17 The first reason is that the number of employees is the Small
Business Administration basis for defining small entities for this industry. The second is that
other ways to define a small entity (e.g., assets or shipments) did not appear to provide any
advantage over the number of employees (see Section 2.4.2.1 for a more detailed discussion).
The distribution of the number of employees by facility indicates a substantial number
of facilities with 125 or fewer employees (Figure 2-10). In keeping with the intent of the RFA, a
three-tiered subdivision was developed for this rulemaking:
• Very small - 0 to 125 employees
• Small - 126 to 750 employees
• Large - more than 750 employees.
"If a facility closes, both production and nonproduction employees will lose their jobs; hence
the definition is based on all employees.
3-88
-------
Taken together, the very small and small categories for the company correspond to the Small
Business Administration definition of a small business entity for the pulp and paper industry.
The additional definitions allow a more detailed examination of smaller entities.
3.5.3 Financial Impact Analysis of Small Entities
.1 Summaty Information for Small Entities - Facility Definition
Table 3-19 indicates that 35 percent of the facilities fall in the very small category; nearly
half are in the small category; and the remaining 16 percent are in the large category. As
anticipated, when a facility is independently owned, there is a much greater likelihood for it to be
a very small facility. Nearly two-thirds of the independently-owned facilities are in the very small
category. Only four percent of the independently-owned facilities are in the large category, The
remaining mills are in the small category. In contrast, about half of the mills that are part of
multifacility organizations are in the small category, and nearly two of every five are large
facilities.
Table 3-20 summarizes the distribution of employees, shipments, and exports among the
regulatory flexibility categories. Large facilities represent only 16 percent of the mill population,
yet they account for over half the employees, 42 to 51 percent of the shipments, and 49 percent
of the exports. Very small facilities account for about 6 percent of employees, 4 to 6 percent of
shipments (value and tons, respectively), but less than 2 percent of the value of exports.
Table 3-21 examines the facility-level ratio analysis by size category. The average gross
income margin for small facilities is negative for all 3 years in the survey. In 1985, at least 25
percent of the mills showed negative gross income margins. This dropped to at least 10 percent
of the mills for 1988 and 1989. An investigation of outliers revealed such occurrences as a
facility that stated in the comments section it was a captive mill that transferred all its production
at cost while the actual data indicate that the transfer price did not cover costs, and a mill that
claimed only 10 percent of its revenues were from pulp, paper, or paperboard. The negative
3-89
-------
TABLE 3-19
COUNTS OF INDEPENDENT AND MULTI-FACILITY HILLS
BY REGULATORY FLEXIBILITY CATEGORY - FACILITY DEFINITION
Multi-
Size Based on Independently Facility All
Employment Owned Percentage Group Percentage Mills Percentage
Very Small
(0 - 125 Employees)
Small
(126 - 750 Employees)
Large
(> 750 Employees)
Total
34 64 148 31 182 35 •
17 32 239 51 256 49
2 4 84 18 86 16
53 100 471 100 524 100 ,
D:\SHALLBUS\COMPANY\SIZE.OUT
Note: Only 524 facilities are included because some mills are dummy mills, have changed
ownership since 1989 and therefore didn't have information for^the questionnaire, have begun
production since 1989, or had contractor-supplied labor.
3-90
-------
o
0
a>
3
8
o
73
£
T3
P
CD
01
ct>
O)
s?
o
o
is
•§1
°"9
ha
lor-
1
SI
^ cc
« 01
8
CO CNt
O
CXI
ri
UJ
_i
CD
<
t—
if
n 75
U. O
= E
CO UJ
E m
c/3 CM
Is.
E
UJ
E CM
co C-
Large
(> 750 Em
BUS\
w S ^1
as 5
*" "C
^ —,
(C ^
^ £
-Q CL
"O C
If
U
to -c
» £
'tr re
1 =
— .0
CD >. C7
Not
O
th
3-91
-------
TABLE 3-21
BASELINE FACILITY-LEVEL RATIO ANALYSIS
REGULATORY FLEXIBILITY CATEGORIES - FACILITY DEFINITION
Ratio
Category
Baseline Value
1985
1988
1989
Percent
Variation
Mean
Gross Income Margin
Return on Assets
Current Ratio
Net Working Capital
($000)
Very Small
Small
Large
All
Very Small
Small
Large
All
Very Small
Small
Large
All
Very Small
Small
Large
All
Net Working Capital/ Very Small
Total Assets Small
Large
All
Median
Gross Income Margin
Return on Assets
Current Ratio
Net Working Capital
(5000)
Very Small
Small
Large
All
Very Small
Small
Large
All
Very Small
Small
Large
All
Very Small
Small
Large
All
3.1%
-0.2%
7.0%
2.1%
30.7%
9.6%
13.0%
17.0%
4.72
2.62
2.15
3.16
$1.195
$2.733
$19,098
$5.275
21.5%
15.8%
9.1%
16.4%
7.3%
-7.7%
18.4%
1.8%
29.7%
34.8%
22.6%
31.0%
3.46
2.51
2.03
2.72
$1,475
$4,916
$17,629
$5,948
17.7%
9.8%
6.9%
12.0%
7.4%
-11.1%
18.8%
0.3%
39.9%
30.3%
23.0%
32.3%
3.83
3.32
2.08
3.26
$1,037
$3,445
$19,716
$5,392
15.2%
7.7%
7.9%
10.3%
Net Working Capital/ Very Small
Total Assets Small
Large
All
5.7%
5,4%
8.0%
5.7%
11 1%
78%
10,5%
95%
209
1.82
1 71
1 85
$667
$2.926
$13.593
$2.211
19 1%
99%
61%
1 1 0%
6.8%
14.6%
19.4%
1 1 ,6%
11.3%
20.6%
18.4%
17.3%
1.98
1.81
1 77
1 84
$709
$4.434
$17.652
$2.778
18 2%
10 2%
66%
98%
8.2%
13.2%
20.2%
12.3%
16.6%
18.1%
18.1%
17.5%
1.88
1.75
1.76
1.81
$628
$4.224
$19.084
$2,284
12.9%
8.7%
6.1%
8.8%
59.0%
-4588.5%
62.6%
87.9%
25.4%
72.3%
43.6%
47.6%
26.8%
24.4%
5.6%
16.4%
29.7%
44.4%
10.6%
11.3%
29.4%
51.0%
24.2%
37.2%
30.6%
62.7%
60.3%
53.2%
33.5%
62.4%
42.8%
45.9%
9.8%
3.7%
3.2%
1.7%
11.5%
34.0%
28.8%
20.4%
32.3%
14.3%
7.4%
20.5%
Notes: Includes independent, single-facility, and multi-facility entities.
There are 523 mills in the analysis,
D:\SMALLBUS\M RATIOS. WK3
05-Aug-93
3-92
-------
value seen for the average gross income margin is an example where data for the ratio analysis
will vary dramatically between the facility level and the business entity level. These data also
indicate that there will be a large number of mills that are projected to close before the addition
of incremental pollution control costs.
The median gross income margin and median return on assets indicate that very small
facilities had more favorable business conditions in 1988 and 1989 than in 1985; the improvement
was less than was seen for small and large facilities. For small facilities, the median return on
assets nearly tripled from 1985 to 1988. The median current ratio remains stable for all
categories for all survey years. The median current ratio for very small facilities is consistently
slightly higher than for the other categories. A very small facility may need a higher current
ratio in order to have a sufficient amount of working capital to finance day-to-day operations.
The distinction between the categories is most apparent in the median amount of net working
capital. Small facilities have about four times the amount of net working capital as very small
facilities while large facilities have between four to five times the net working capital as small
facilities. Net working capital forms the highest percentage of total assets for very small facilities
and the smallest percentage for large facilities.
333.2 Summary Information for Small Entities - Business Definition
Table 3-22 indicates that 32 percent of the business entities fall in the very small category;
another 42 percent are in the small category; and the remaining 26 percent are in the large
category. The distribution among size categories is the same for independent operations because
the facility and business entity coincide; nearly two-thirds of the independently-owned facilities
are in the very small category. In contrast, only one of every five non-independent companies
are in the very small category. For non-independent businesses, 46 percent are in the small
category and the remaining 34 percent are in the large category. Using only the Small Business
Administration definition for small entity, large entities account for 26 percent of the population.
Table 3-23 summarizes the distribution of employees, shipments, and exports among the
regulatory flexibility categories on a company basis. Large companies represent only 26 percent
3-93
-------
TABLE 3-22
COUNTS OF INDEPENDENT AND MULTI-FACILITY MILLS
BY REGULATORY FLEXIBILITY CATEGORY - BUSINESS DEFINITION
Non-
Size Based on Independently Independently All
Employment Owned Percentage Owned Percentage Hills Percentage
Very Small
CO - 125 Employees)
Small
C126 - 750 Employees)
Large
(> 750 Employees)
Total
34 64 29 20 63 32
17 32 66 46 83 42
2 4 49 34 50 26
53 100 144 100 196 100
D:\SMALLBUS\COMPANY\SIZE.OUT
Note: This analysis includes 196 companies. Three companies are not included because they
have begun production since 1989 or had contractor-supplied labor.
3-94
-------
o>
IN
8
co
n
m
OL
sJ
<
O
m
<
en
<
99
X
in
LU
DC
*~~. Q)
LU
CO O
a. a)
E S
O CD
O O
CO eg
e-T
CD CD
E «N
m *^
.
LU
iCL
i
<
12
Q
3-95
-------
of the population, yet they account for 86 percent of the employees, 76 to 88 percent of the
shipments, and 87 percent of the exports.
Table 3-24 examines the ratio analysis by size category based on business entities. The
patterns seen in the data are similar to those seen at the facility level (Table 3-20). The average
net income margin for very small entities is negative in 1985, while large entities had a margin of
nearly 6 percent. The data for all ratios indicate that the industry downturn had begun by the
end of 1989; 1988 tends to be the better year. This is consistent with the observations of other
industry analysts (DeKing et al., 1990).
The distinction between the size categories is most apparent when we compare the
median net working capital and net working capital-to-total assets. Very small companies have
about $1 million in net working capital, yet this forms between 25 to 40 percent of its total
assets. Small companies have about $5 to $9 million in net working capital, but this forms only
between 15 to 20 percent of its total assets. The median amount of net working capital for a
large company ranges from $60 to $100 million over the survey period. Although this is nearly
60 to 100 times the amount of net working capital for a very small entity, it forms only 8 to 10
percent of the total assets for the company. The median values for the other ratios—net income
margin, return on assets, current ratio, debt-to-assets, and times interest earned—show far less
stratification among the categories.
3.5.4 Market Impact Analysis of Small Entities
The results of the market impact model can be used to evaluate the impact of the
proposed regulations on groups of small and large facilities and small and large companies. The
market impact model provides facility-level impacts that are mapped to company-level data to
estimate impacts on companies. For the purpose of evaluating market impact analysis results
small facilities are defined as 126 to 750 employees, and very small facilities are defined as less
than 125 employees. In addressing small business impacts at the company level, the SBA size
standards will be employed. Thus, the company-level analysis will consist of a large category,
defined as greater than 750 employees, and a small category, defined as less than 750 employees.
3-96
-------
TABLE 3-24
BASELINE BUSINESS ENTITY-LEVEL RATIO ANALYSIS
REGULATORY FLEXIBILITY CATEGORIES - BUSINESS DEFINITION
Ratio
Mean
Net Income Margin
Return on Assets
Current Ratio
Net Working Capital
($000)
Net Working Capital/
Category
Very Small
Small
Large
All
Very Small
Small
Large
All
Very Small
Small
Large
All
Very Small
Small
Large
All
Very Small
Total Assets Small
Debt/Asset Ratio
Times Interest Earned
Median
Net Income Margin
Return on Assets
Current Ratio
Net Working Capital
(SOOOj
Net Working Capital/
Large
All
Very Small
Small
Large
All
Very Small
Small
Large
All
Very Small
Small
Large
All
Very Small
Small
Large
All
Very Small
Small
Large
All
Very Small
Small
Large
All
Very Small
Total Assets Small
Debt/Asset Ratio
Times Interest Earned
Large
All
Very Small
Small
Large
All
Very Small
Small
Large
Alt
Baseline Parameter
1985 1988
-1.0%
1.2%
5.6%
1.8%
6.9%
1.5%
6.5%
4.6%
7.04
216
1.87
355
$2.825
$40,820
$100.924
$46,172
343%
163%
11.1%
20.3%
43.4%
580%
50.9%
51.5%
250
405
657
455
40%
43%
4 1%
42%
69%
54%
54%
58%
266
1 83
1 69
190
$971
$556S
$60427
$5584
398%
180%
103%
183%
357%
50 7%
51 6%
502%
5 3
66
63
6i
5.5%
6.2%
7.2%
6.2%
10,4%
9,0%
8.6%
9.3%
3.16
2.44
1.75
2.48
$2,714
$62,349
$165.886
$70,231
291%
197%
94%
20.0%
53.6%
61 1%
55.9%
57.2%
143
35 1
477
342
37%
46%
72%
53%
92%
68%
89%
85%
232
20i
1 b4
1 91
$89>.
So«.l
Sh& 230
S"090
298%
19 '!%
9 1%
17 V*
W 9%
f.?. •>.%
l?b%
M 2%
6 3
69
109
ob
1989
3.5%
4.7%
6.1%
4.7%
10.7%
6.3%
7.3%
8.0%
3.17
2.29
1.72
2.43
$2,416
$51,501
$155,766
$62,005
26.3%
174%
9.2%
18.2%
539%
62.7%
577%
584%
288
-151
228
21 1
38%
32%
64%
50%
84%
52%
6 7%
65%
20«
I 82
1 57
1 79
$103?
$b472
S10040C
$584-
K 1%
154%
8 1%
1J2%
M <•%
M ;%
4
-------
The terms facility, establishment, plant, and mill are synonymous in this analysis and refer to the
physical location where products are manufactured. Likewise, the terms company and firm are
synonymous and refer to the legal business entity that owns one or more facilities.
33.4.1 Facility-Level Analysis
In the case of the pulp and paper industry, small businesses will probably incur an
economic impact because all facilities react to the regulation-driven changes in market prices
resulting in changes in facility-level revenues, costs, and earnings before interest, depreciation,
and taxes (EBIDT). The market impact model analysis generates information that can be used
to assess these impacts. Measures of economic impact on which an analysis at the facility-level is
based should reflect changes in operating status and employment, changes in revenues, costs, and
EBIDT, and the relative size of the regulatory costs to baseline revenues, costs, and EBIDT.
The facility-level analysis includes the following impact measures:
Percentage of small mills predicted to close with the regulation versus the
percentage of large mills
Distribution of predicted employment changes with the regulation across small
and large mills
Percentage change from baseline in product revenues, total costs of production,
and EBIDT for small versus large mills
Annual compliance costs (annualized capital and annual operating) as a
percentage of total revenues and total costs of production for small versus large
mills, and
Annual compliance costs (annualized capital and annual operating) as a
percentage of EBIDT for small versus large mills.
The baseline values for revenues, costs, and EBIDT at the facility level are determined
from the baseline data in the market impact model, and the percentage changes due to the
regulation are obtained after imposing the regulatory costs and allowing markets to adjust.
3-98
-------
Baseline Facility Size Distribution. Table 3-25 indicates that 85.2 percent of the facilities
fall in the small combination group, while the remaining 14.8 percent are in the large category.
Within the small combination group, small facilities account for 54 percent and very small
facilities the remaining 46 percent. As expected, a facility is more likely to be in the small
combination group when it is independently owned and operated as opposed to when it is part of
a multifacility group. Almost 97 percerit of the independently owned facilities are in the small
combination group, while only 3 percent are in the large category. Alternatively, roughly 83
percent of the mills that are part of multifacility groups are part of the small combination group,
and over 17 percent are categorized as large.
Facility Employment. As shown in Table 3-26, industry production and non-production
employment estimates for 1989 are almost evenly divided across small combination group and
large facilities. Small combination group facilities employ roughly 49 percent of industry
workers, while the remaining 51 percent of the industry's workforce is employed at large
facilities. Within the small combination group, small facilities account for over 85 percent, while
very small facilities account for the remaining 15 percent. Facilities that are part of a
multifacility group employ the vast majority of the estimated 217,628 production and non-
production employees, accounting for over 90 percent of this total. As expected, independently
owned and operated facilities account for a very small percentage, only 9 percent, of
employment. Employment changes associated with regulating the industry are determined by the
facility-level responses in the market impact model. The changes in employment result from
both mill closures and production changes at mills continuing to operate with the regulations.
Product Revenues. Production Cost, and Earnings Before Interest Depreciation and
Taxes (EBIDT). Additional indicators of the severity of the economic impact on small facilities
include the changes in product revenues, total costs of production, and EBIDT. All facilities in
the market impact model react to the regulation-driven changes in market prices—deciding
whether to produce and, if so, at what level. These reactions to the market outcomes result in
changes in facility-level revenues, variable production costs, and EBIDT. Comparing the
distributional changes in facility-level revenues, costs, and EBIDT across small and large facilities
indicates whether any disproportional impact exists across these populations because of
regulation.
3-99
-------
TABLE 3-25
INDEPENDENT AND MULTIFACILITY MILLS BY SIZE: 1989
BASELINE VALUES
Size based on employment
Small Combination Group
(<750)
Small (<750&> 125)
Very Small (<.125)
Large (>750)
Total
Independently
owned
Number
94
44
50
3
97
Percentage
96.9
45.4
51.5
3.1
100.0
Multifacility
group
Number Percentage
388
217
171
81
82.7
46.3
36.4
17.3
469 100.0
Total
Number
482
261
221
84
566
Percentage
85.2
46.1
39.1
14.8
100.0
Source: EPA survey.
3-100
-------
TABLE 3-26
EMPLOYMENT OF INDEPENDENT AND MULTIFACILITY MILLS
BY SIZE: 1989 BASELINE VALUES
Size based on employment
Small Combination Group (<750)
Small (<750& >125)
Very Small (< 125)
Large (>750)
Total
Independently
owned
Number Percentage
17,698 83.3
14,391 67.7
3,307 15.6
3,549 16.7
21,247 100.0
Multifacility
group
Number Percentage
88,701 45.2
76,109 38.8
12,592 6.4
107,680 54.8
196^81 100.0
Total
Number
106,399
90,500
15,899
111,229
217,628
Percentage
48.9
41.6
7.3
51.5
100.0
Source: EPA survey.
3-101
-------
Annual Compliance Costs. The relative severity of the regulations can also be measured
by comparing the ratios of annual compliance costs to total revenues, total costs, and EBIDT
across small and large facilities. Although all facilities react to the regulation-driven market
changes, only a subset of the facilities in the pulp and paper industry incur direct annual costs of
compliance. The significance of these costs to directly affected facilities can be measured in
terms of total revenues, total costs, and EBIDT. Comparing these ratios across small and large
facilities indicates whether any disproportional direct burden of compliance exists across these
populations.
3.5.4.2 Company-Level Analysis
A regulatory action to reduce pollutant discharges from facilities manufacturing pulp and
paper will potentially affect the business entities that own the regulated facilities. Facilities, or
mills, comprise a site of land with plant and equipment that combine inputs (raw materials,
energy, and labor) to produce outputs (pulp, paper, and paperboard). Companies, or firms, that
own these facilities are legal business entities that have the capacity to conduct business
transactions and make business decisions that affect the facility.
Potentially affected firms include entities that own facilities that manufacture pulp, paper,
and paperboard. For the base year of 1989, the market impact model identifies 214 companies
potentially affected by the regulation. However, one firm lacked data necessary for inclusion in
the analysis. Thus, the firm-level analysis includes 213 firms owning 565 facilities.
The baseline financial profile was based on complete financial data from EPA's National
Census for 151 of the 213 companies included in the analysis, while the baseline financial profile
of the remaining 62 firms is supplemented or constructed using data from American Business
Information (ABI) and Dun and Bradstreet's (D&B's) Industry Norms and Key Business Ratios
(EPA, 1991; ABI, 1993; Dun's, 1991). These sources were incorporated because of incomplete
financial data, i.e., missing balance sheet data, in the National Census for 41 companies and
missing financial data, neither income statement or balance sheet information, for 21 companies.
3-102
-------
The measures of economic impact on which the company-level analysis is based reflect
changes in the number of operating mills and employment, changes in profitability, and the
change in the likelihood of financial failure (bankruptcy, as measured by the Altman Z-score).
The firm-level analysis includes the following impact measures:
Percentage of mills owned by small and large firms predicted to close with the
regulation
Distribution of predicted employment changes with the regulation across small
and large firms
Changes from baseline in key measures of profitability (return on sales, return on
assets, and return on equity) for small versus large firms, and
Changes from baseline in the likelihood of financial failure or bankruptcy (as
measured by Altman's Z'-score) for small versus large firms (Altman, 1983).
Companies In The Analysis. Companies in this analysis include those owned directly by
the shareholders/owners and those owned by a "parent" company. Figure 3-13 shows the chain of
ownership may be as simple as one facility owned by one company or as complex as multiple
facilities owned by subsidiary companies.
Business entities that own pulp and paper manufacturing facilities will generally be one of
three types of entities:
• Sole proprietorships
• Partnerships, and
• Corporations.
Each type has its own legal and financial characteristics that may have a bearing on how firms
are affected by the regulatory alternatives. Table 3-27 provides information of the legal form of
ownership of firms for the relevant SIC codes.
3-103
-------
Parent Company
' h +.&, "~~ •"•»'• *
Other Companies
or
Legal Entities
* . _ ••„ . ' „
Subsidiary
Company
(Direct Owner)
' " • A ' ,-„..••-"
r ~
Facility
IWliillljlplllullVl^WM^IIIW'IIIW^^
A
'T
-fft
Parent Company
» s v^y 4
[ t „ , ~ ' -
Subsidiary
Company
(Direct Owner)
^':B»?.j.,lV> .*;-> •^-.'^ft^'^.1 >^< >A« x x*
Facility
'^ Parent Company
jv V v i
3
h* I
1
•5 Facility |
B C
Figure 3-13. Chain of ownership.
3-104
-------
w
S3
H
52 «-
g oj\
fa
fa ^"*
° H
r- |p
*"? H §
i ~i
os ^
0 P
fa 5
o ^
OS D
O CL,
fa
J
o
w
o
H
c
.2
1
I
UH
o
o
e
_
Ofi
•[
VH
-. C .^. —
| to S 3
£
en oo
T—l C^
o o
0 0
o o
en oo
i— < t~~
^-i
0\
o
o
o
T— t
ON
goo
EM "
^2* ^ «3
"S "^ £^
"° tS ^ C
CO Qi J^ C
1 t I S
8. K S «?
cS
eu,
•
ON
ON
U
O
Q
oJ
o
3
0
CO
3-105
-------
The 213 companies identified in the market impact model are listed in Table 2-31. The
number is firms is larger than the 135 reported in the 1987 Census of Manufacturing for "Pulp and
Paper Mills" because it includes some firms listed under "Other Paper and Allied Products."
Company-Level Employment and Size. To arrive at employment estimates for companies
in the market impact model we aggregated facility-level employment to the firm level because the
1990 National Census did not include company-level employment data. However, for some firms
this measure of employment does not accurately reflect their employment, and thus firm size,
because they may own facilities outside of the pulp and paper industry. To avoid
misclassification, particularly in the case of incorrectly categorizing large firms as small, we
incorporated employment data from ABI on parent companies included in the relevant SIC
codes (i.e., 2611, 2621, and 2631). Based on these data 150 firms, or 70.4 percent, are
categorized as small, while the remaining 63 firms, or 29.6 percent, are in the large category.
Small firms employ an average of only 193 workers. Large firms have a much higher number of
employees across all operations-averaging 9,896 per firm.
Firms may differ in size for one or both of the following reasons:
• First, pulp and paper facilities vary widely by size. All else being equal, firms with
large facilities are larger than firms with small facilities.
• Second, firms vary in the number of facilities they own. All else being equal,
firms with more facilities arc larger than those with fewer facilities.
Control economies are typically facility related rather than firm related. For example, a
firm with six uncontrolled facilities with an average annual receipt of $1 million per facility may
face approximately six times the control capital requirements of a firm with one uncontrolled
facility whose receipts.total $6 million per year. Alternatively, two firms with the same number
of facilities facing approximately the same control capital costs may be financially affected very
differently if the facilities of one are larger than those of the other.
Table 3-28 shows the average size of facility (based on 1989 total employment level)
represented in each company size category. As expected, larger firms own larger facilities on
average. Table 3-29 shows the distribution of firms bv the number of facilities owned. A slight
3-106
-------
TABLE 3-28
AVERAGE SIZE OF FACILITY BY FIRM
SIZE CATEGORY: 1989s
Firm size
based on employment
(1989)
Total employment
at facUities owned
Total number of
facilities owned
Average
employment per
facility
Small (< 750)
Large (>750)
Total, all firms
27,136
190,492
217,628
211
354
566
129
538
384
"Facility size is measured as total employment in 1989.
Source: EPA survey.
TABLE 3-29
DISTRIBUTION OF FIRMS BY NUMBER OF
FACILITIES OWNED: 1989
Number of facilities owned per firm
Firm size based on employment
Small (< 750)
Large (> 750)
Total, all firms
1
116
19
135
2 to 3
26
13
39
OverS
8
31
39
Total
150
63
213
Source: EPA survey.
3-107
-------
correlation appears to exist between the number of pulp and paper manufacturing facilities
owned and the size of the firm. The average number of facilities owned by small firms is 1.4
(213 facilities -5- 150 firms) as compared to an average of 5.6 facilities (354 facilities •*• 63 firms)
owned by large firms. However, nonpulp and paper facilities are not reflected in this
distribution.
Issues of Vertical and Horizontal Integration. Vertical integration is a potentially
important dimension in firm-level impact analysis because the regulation could affect a vertically
integrated firm on several levels. For example, the regulation may affect companies for whom
the manufacture of pulp and paper is not the company's primary focus but rather is an input into
the company's other production processes such as construction, print media, and food products.
A regulation that increases the cost of manufacturing pulp and paper for vertically integrated
firms will also affect the cost of producing the primary products. The market impacts on
nonpulp and paper products are not estimated in the market impact model analysis. Table 3-30
shows the range of industries represented by firms that own pulp and paper facilities by SIC
code.
Horizontal integration is also a potentially important dimension in firm-level impact
analysis for either or both of two reasons:
First, a diversified firm may own facilities in unaffected industries. This type of
diversification would help mitigate the firm-level financial impacts of the
regulation.
Second, a diversified firm could be indirectly as well as directly affected by the
regulation. For example, if a firm is diversified in manufacturing pollution control
equipment (an unlikely scenario), the regulation could indirectly and favorably
affect it.
Figure 3-14 shows the share of total receipts from business activities other than pulp and
paper manufacturing for firms in each size category. Firms in the large size category receive
slightly more than 50 percent of their revenues from other activities. Conversely, firms in the
small size category receive the vast majority of their revenues from business activities other than
pulp and paper manufacturing.
3-108
-------
TABLE 3-30
SIC LISTINGS FOR FIRMS OWNING PULP AND PAPER MANUFACTURING FACILITIES
SIC Code Industry and product description
2087
2099
2411
2421
2429
2448
2499
2611
2621
2631
2641
2643
2645
2647
2649
2651
2653
2654
2655
2661
2671
2672
2674
2679
2741
2812
2816
2819
2841
2851
2861
2869
2952
3081
3083
3087
3275
3296
3471
Ravoring extracts & syrups, n.e.c.
Food preparations, n.e.c.
Logging camps and logging contractors
Sawmills & planing mills, general
Special product sawmills, n.e.c.
Wood pallets & skids
Wood products, n.e.c.
Pulp Mills
Paper Mills, except building paper
Paperboard Mills
Paper coating & glazing
Bags, except textile bags
Die-cut paper & board
Sanitary paper products
Converted paper products, n.e.c.
Folding paperboard boxes
Corrugated & solid fiber boxes
Sanitary food containers
Fiber cans, tubes, drums, & similar products
Building paper and board mills
Paper coated & laminated, packaging
Coated & laminated paper, n.e.c.
Uncoated paper & multiwall bags
Converted paper & paperboard products
Miscellaneous publishing
Alkalies & chlorine
Inorganic pigments
Industrial inorganic chemicals, n.e.c.
Soap & other detergents, except specialty cleaners
Paint & allied products
Gum & wood chemicals
Industrial organic chemicals, n.e.c.
Asphalt felts & coatings
Unsupported plastics film & sheet
Laminated plastics plate, sheet, & profile shapes
Custom compounding of purchased plastics resins
Gypsum products
Mineral wool
Plating and polishing
Source: EPA survey.
3-109
-------
Percentage of Total Receipts from EJusiness Activities Other than
Pulp and Paper Manufacturing
80 -r 78'8
70 --
60 --
50 --
40 --
30 --
20 --
10 --
0 --
57.6
52.3
Small Large Total
Company Size Category
Figure 3-14. Total receipts from business activities other than pulp and
paper manufacturing.
3-110
-------
Computing Company-Level Impacts. Company-level impact results are generated by
aggregating changes at the facility level and incorporating the changes into the 1989 baseline
financial statements of each firm. The baseline financial profile was based on complete financial
data from EPA's National Census for 151 of the 213 companies included in the analysis, while
the baseline financial profile of the remaining 69 firms is supplemented or constructed using data
from American Business Information (ABI, 1993) and Dun and Bradstreet's (D&B's) Industry
Norms and Key Business Ratios (Dun's, 1991). These sources were incorporated because of
incomplete financial data, i.e., missing balance sheet data, in the National Census for 41
companies and missing financial data, neither income statement or balance sheet information, for
21 companies.
We made several adjustments to the financial statements of each firm to account for the
regulation-induced changes at all facilities owned by the firm. In the annual income statement,
firm revenues and costs are both directly and indirectly affected because all facilities react to the
adjustments in market prices associated with regulation. We adjusted sales revenue by the
aggregate change in product revenue for facilities owned by the firm. We altered the costs of
goods sold by the aggregate change in production costs across facilities owned by the firm. The
change in production costs includes both the annual compliance costs (operating and
maintenance costs plus annual capital expenses) and variable cost changes due to output
adjustments.
In the balance sheet, changes occur only to those firms directly affected by the regulation
and are determined.by the manner in which firms acquire the pollution control equipment.
Directly affected firms face three choices in funding the acquisition of capital equipment required
to comply with the regulations. These choices include:
• Debt financing
• Equity financing, or
• A mixture of debt and equity financing.
3-111
-------
Debt financing involves obtaining additional funds from lenders who are not owners of
the firm: they include buyers of bonds, banks, or other lending institutions. Equity financing
involves obtaining additional funds from the owners of the firm: proprietors, partners, or
shareholders. Each source differs in its exposure to risk, in its taxation, and its costs. In general,
debt financing is more risky for the firm than equity financing because of the legal obligation of
repayment, while borrowing debt can allow a firm to reduce its weighted average cost of capital
because of the deducibility of interest on debt for state and federal income tax purposes. The
outcome is that there exists a tradeoff associated with debt financing for each firm that depends
on their tax rates, their asset structures, and their inherent riskiness.
Leverage indicates the degree to which the firm's assets have been supplied by, and hence
are owned by, creditors versus owners. Leverage should be in an acceptable range, indicating
that the firm is using enough debt financing to take advantage of the low cost of debt, but not so
much that current or potential creditors are uneasy about the ability of the firm to repay its debt.
The debt ratio (d) is a common measure of leverage that divides all debt, long and short term, by
total assets. Capital structure does not appear to have a significant impact on firm value over a
wide range of debt ratio values. Consequently, we assume that the current capital structure, as
measured by the debt ratio, reflects the optimal capital structure for each firm. Thus, we use
each firm's debt ratio for 1989 to determine the amount of capital expenditures on pollution
control technology that will be debt financed.
Thus, in the 'assets side of the balance sheet of affected firms, current assets decline by (1
- d) times the total installed capital cost (EK), while the value of property, plant, and equipment
increases by the total installed capital cost (i.e., the value of the pollution control equipment).
Thus, the overall increase in a firm's total assets is equal to that fraction of the total installed
capital cost that is not paid out of current assets (i.e., d EK).
The liabilities side of the balance sheet is affected because firms enter new legal
obligations to repay that fraction of the total installed capital cost that is assumed to be debt
financed (i.e., d EK). Long-term debt, and thus total liabilities, of the firm is increased by this
dollar amount. Owner's equity, or net worth at these firms is unchanged because of the
offsetting increases in both total assets and total liabilities. However, working capital at each
3-112
-------
affected firm, defined as current assets minus current liabilities, unambiguously falls because of
the decline in current assets.
Comparison of the baseline and post-compliance financial profiles of firms in the U.S.
pulp and paper industry provides indicators of the potential disparity of economic impacts across
small and large firms. These indicators include the key measures of profitability (return on sales,
return on assets, and return on equity) and changes in the likelihood of financial failure or
bankruptcy (as measured by Altman's Z'-score).
Company-Level Profitability Measures. Profitability is the most comprehensive measure
of the firm's performance because it measures the combined effects of liquidity, asset
management, and debt management. Analyzing profitability is useful because it helps evaluate
both the incentive and ability of firms in the pulp and paper industry to incur the capital and
operating costs required for compliance. More profitable firms have more incentive than less
profitable firms to comply because the annual returns to doing business are greater. Ir^the
extreme, a single-facility firm earning zero profit has no incentive to comply with a regulation
imposing any positive costs unless the entire cost of the regulation can be passed along to
consumers. This same firm may also be less able to comply because its poor financial position
makes it difficult to obtain funds through either debt or equity financing.
Several ratios are commonly used to measure profitability, including return on assets,
return on equity, and return on sales. For all these measures, higher values are unambiguously
preferred over lower values. Table 3-31 shows the ratios used in the market impact analysis to
measure the financial viability of firms in terms of profitability.
Baseline and with-regulation profitability are evaluated using comparative analysis of key
measures of a firm's profitability. Comparative analysis is a widely accepted way of summarizing
the profitability of a firm using ratios reported on the firm's financial statements. This
comparative analysis evaluates the profitability of potentially affected firms before and after
regulation by comparing the firm's key measures of profitability with specific industry benchmark
ratios reported in D&B's Industry Norms and Key Business Ratios. Tables 3-32 through 3-34
3-113
-------
TABLE 3-31
KEY MEASURES OF FIRM PROFITABILITY
Measure of Profitability
Formula for Calculation
Return on Sales
Return on Assets
Return on Equity
Net Income
Sales
Net Income
Total Assets
Net Iricome
Owner's Equity
3-114
-------
TABLE 3-32
UPPER QUARTILE BENCHMARK RATIOS
Key measures of profitability
SIC
code.
2611
2621
2631
Source: Duns, 1991.
Return on
sales
0.108
0.086
0.081
Return on
assets
0.117
0.112
0.110
TABLE 3-33
Return on
equity
0.183
0.226
0.202
MEDIAN BENCHMARK RATIOS
Key measures of profitability
SIC
code.
2611
2621
2631
Source: Duns, 1991.
Return on
sales
0.096
0.049
0.032
LOWER
Return on
assets
0.097
0.065
0.078
TABLE 3-34
QUARTILE BENCHMARK RATIOS
Return on
equity
0.169
0.157
0.127
Key measures of profitability
SIC
code
2611
2621
2631
Return on
sales
0.077
0.021
0.016
Return on
assets
0.085
0.038
0.020
Return on
equity
0.154
0.096
0.084
oource: uuns,
3-115
-------
report the benchmark upper quartile, median, and lower quartile measures used to evaluate the
profitability of potentially affected firms in the pulp and paper industry (identified by SIC).
In Tables 3-35 through 3-37, we compare the profitability measures computed for
potentially affected firms to the benchmark ratios reported in Tables 3-32 through 3-34. For the
base year of analysis, between 60 and 74 percent of the firms in the small size category and 74.6
to 79.4 percent of firms in the large size category have a profitability measure that is below the
industry upper quartile. Between 48 and 55.3 percent of the firms in the small size category and
between 41.3 and 54 percent of firms in the large size category have a profitability measure
below the industry median in 1989. Further, between 32 and 37.3 percent of the firms
represented in the small category have a profitability measure below the industry lower quartile
in 1989. Alternatively, 28.6 to 33.3 percent of firms in the large size category fall below the
benchmark lower quartile value in 1989. Based on the data contained in these figures, firms in
the large size category appear to be no more profitable on average than other firms in the
industry.
After imposition of regulation, a reduction in overall profitability for each size category
would be seen as an increase in the percentage of firms below each benchmark measure.
Alternatively, an increase in overall profitability would be indicated by a decrease in the
percentage of firms below each benchmark measure with regulation.
Bankruptcy Analysis. A facility, or establishment, is a site of land with a plant and
equipment that combine inputs like materials, energy, and labor to produce outputs, like pulp,
paper, and paperboard. Firms are legal business entities that, in this context, own one or more
facilities. This distinction between facilities and firms is an important one in discussing the
economic viability of facilities and firms. In the market impact analysis the viability of the facility
is determined by economic criteria - close the mill if marginal revenue (price) is below marginal
cost. Alternatively, the viability of the firms as legal entities is conditional on their ability to
meet their legal obligations.
Altman draws the distinction between economic failure and bankruptcy. His definition of
economic failure is consistent with the mill closure decision included in the market impact model.
3-116
-------
TABLE 3-35
PERCENTAGE OF FIRMS BELOW INDUSTRY BENCHMARK RATIOS IN BASELINE:
RETURN ON SALES
Percentage
less than
Benchmark ratios
Upper quartile
Median
Lower quartile
Small firms
Baseline (%)
74.0
55.3
32.0
Large firms
Baseline (%)
79.4
42.9
28.6
All firms
Baseline (%)
75.6
51.6
31.0
TABLE 3-36
PERCENTAGE OF FIRMS BELOW INDUSTRY BENCHMARK RATIOS IN BASELINE:
RETURN ON ASSETS
Percentage
less than
Small firms
Baseline (%)
Large firms
Baseline (%)
All firms
Baseline (%)
Benchmark ratios
Upper quartile
Median
Lower quartile
70.0
56.7
37.3
77.8
54.0
33.3
72.3
55.9
36.2
3-117
-------
TABLE 3-37
PERCENTAGE OF FIRMS BELOW INDUSTRY BENCHMARK RATIOS IN BASELINE:
RETURN ON EQUITY
Percentage
less than
Small firms
Large firms
All firms
Baseline (%)
Baseline (%)
Baseline (%)
Benchmark ratios
Upper quartile
Median
Lower quartile
60.0
48.0
35.3
74.6
41.3
33.3
64.3
46.0
34.7
3-118
-------
Economic failure results from the inability of invested capital (i.e., the facility) to continually
cover its variable costs through revenue. Bankruptcy can be defined financially or legally, but
both definitions are closely related. Financially, a business is bankrupt when the fair market
value of its total assets is below its total liabilities. Legally, a business can be determined to be
bankrupt when it fails to earn profits sufficient to meet enforceable debts. In such cases, firms
may declare bankruptcy with a new owner taking over the operation of the physical assets (i.e.,
plant, equipment, and land).
The objective of the company-level bankruptcy analysis is to determine the likely effect of
air and water pollution controls on the financial and legal viability of small and large firms within
the pulp and paper industry. Determining whether an increased likelihood of legal bankruptcy,
or business insolvency, will lead to reallocating resources away from the production of pulp and
paper or to reorganizing resources within the pulp and paper industry is outside the scope of this
analysis.
A composite ratio of financial condition, called the Z-score, was computed to characterize
the baseline and with-regulation financial conditions of potentially affected firms. The Z-score,
developed specifically for manufacturing firms, is a multidiscriminant function used to assess
bankruptcy potential (Altman, 1983). The advantage of the Z-score model over traditional ratio
analysis is its simultaneous consideration of liquidity, asset management, debt management,
profitability, and market value. The function is given in Eq. 1:
Z = 1.2X, + 1.4X2 + 0.33X3 + 0.06X4 + 0.999X5 (1)
where
Z
Xt
X,
X3
X4
overall index
working capital/total assets
retained earnings/total assets
earnings before interest and taxes/total assets
market value of equity/book value of total debt
sales/total assets.
The market value component (X») uses stock price data; consequently, the Z-score is
only applicable to firms with publicly traded stock. For this analysis, we used a modified
3-119
-------
function substituting the book value of equity for the market value in X4 referred to as the Z'-
score, given in Eq. 2:
Z' = 0.717XJ + 0.847X2 + 3.107X3 + 0.42X4 + 0.998X5 (2)
where Z' is the overall index and all other variables are as defined for Z above. The modified
function allows us to investigate privately-held as well as publicly-held firms on an equal basis.
Taken individually, each of the ratios given above is higher for firms in good financial
condition and lower for firms in poor financial condition. Consequently, the greater a firm's
bankruptcy potential, the lower its discriminant score. A Z-score below 1.81 indicates that
bankruptcy is likely; a score above 2.99 indicates that bankruptcy is unlikely. Z-scores between
1.81 and 2.99 are indeterminant. Similarly, a Z'-score below 1.23 indicates that bankruptcy is
likely; a score above 2.90 indicates that bankruptcy is unlikely. Z'-scores between 1.23 and 2.90
are indeterminant.
Table 3-38 shows the 1989 baseline distribution of firms by Z'-score prediction. Financial
failure is likely for 7 percent of firms in the industry. Predicted failure across firm size reveals
that 6 percent of the firms in the small size category, while 9.5 percent of the firms in the large
size category are likely to fail in the baseline. These predicted failure rates do not compare
favorably with average reported failure rates for the U.S. The 1990 failure rate averaged 0.92
percent for all manufacturing firms, 0.49 percent for all service firms, and 0.76 percent for, all
U.S. firms (Dun's, 1991).
A possible explanation for the high failure predictions for firms in the pulp and paper
industry, as measured by the Altman Z'-score, is the capital intensive nature of the industry.
Capital expenditures per year for the industry reached $16.7 billion in 1990 and neared $12
billion in 1991 (Storat, 1992). These capital expenditures are necessary to retool existing plants
and construct new plants, as well as environmental compliance. Almost 60 percent of the
industry's capacity exists in machinery that was either newly installed or extensively rebuilt during
the past ten years—resulting in almost 21 million tons of new capacity since 1980 (Storat, 1992).
The capital outlays for pollution control technology to comply with existing government
3-120
-------
TABLE 3-38
BASELINE BANKRUPTCY PREDICTION BY FIRM SIZE
Z'-score prediction8
All companies
Bankruptcy likely
Indeterminant
Bankruptcy Unlikely
Firm size based on
Small (<750)
150
9
56
85
employment (1989)
Large (>750)
63
6
32
25
Total
213
15
88
110
'Bankruptcy prediction is based on Altman's Z'-score for manufacturing companies. If a
company's Z'-score is < 1.23, the model predicts that bankruptcy is likely. If a company's
Z'-score is > 2.90, the model predicts that bankruptcy is unlikely. Z'-scores between 1.23
and 2.90 fall in the indeterminant range, and the model makes no prediction for these
companies.
Source: EPA survey.
3-121
-------
regulations and in response to public dioxin-related concerns have also increased over the past
few years—exceeding $1 billion per year according to industry sources (Storat, 1992).
The investment in capital, however, also brought along a huge level of debt for many
firms in the industry. The debt incurred over the past ten years is reflected in the financial
statement, and the associated financial ratios, of each firm included this analysis. Consequently,
it is not surprising that the predicted failure rates computed for these firms are significantly
higher than 1990 rates for U.S. firms in general. However, the industry should soon, if not
already, receive the returns on these large investments and reestablish financial strength as
measured by Altman's Z'-score.
3.6 REFERENCES
ABI. 1993. American Business Information, Inc. American business lists. (Online database).
Omaha, Nebraska.
Altman, Edward. 1983. Corporate financial distress. New York: John Wiley and Sons.
Brealy, Richard and Stewart Meyers. 1984. Principles of corporate finance. New York:
McGraw-Hill Book Publishing Company. Second Edition.
CCH. 1991a. Commerce Clearing House, Inc. State tax handbook. Chicago, IL.
CCH. 1991b. Commerce Clearing House, Inc. 1991 master tax guide. Chapter 12. Chicago,
IL.
CEA. 1993. Council of Economic Advisers. Economic report of the president. Washington,
DC. Tables B-56 and B-69.
DcKing, Noel, Regina McGrath. Debra Garcia, Rob Galin. and Will Mies. U.S. paper industry
is prepared for cyclical slowdown this year. 1990. Pulp & Paper. January, pp. 57-60.
DOC. 1991. U.S. Department of Commerce. Bureau of Census. 1987 census of
manufacturing, subject series: Type of organization. Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Printing Office.
DOC. 1992. Department of Commerce. Regional multipliers: A user handbook for the
regional input-output modeling system (RIMS II). Washington, DC: Bureau of Economic
Analysis, U.S. DOC.
3-122
-------
Dun's. 1991. Dun's Analytical Services. Industry norms and key business ratios. Dun and
Bradstreet Credit Services.
ENR. 1993. Engineering News Report. Construction cost index. March 29. p. 34-35.
EPA. 1991. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 1990 national census of pulp, paper,1 and
paperboard manufacturing facilities. Washington, DC. October, 31, 1991.
EPA. 1992a. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. Total Cost Assessment: Accelerating
industrial pollution prevention through innovative project financial analysis. Washington, D.C.
Office of Pollution Prevention and Toxics.
EPA. 1992b. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. EPA guidelines for implementing the
regulatory flexibility act. Washington, D.C. Office of Policy, Planning, and Evaluation. April.
Fortune. 1991. Fortune forecast. June 3. pp. 22-23.
IRS. 1988. The Research Institute of America, Inc. .,The complete internal revenue code. New
York, NY. July edition.
Mies, Will, Debra Garcia, Noel DeKing, Robert Galin, Sophie Wilkinson, Mark Weintraub, and
Jim McLaren. 1992. U.S. paper industry will benefit from economic revival this year. Pulp &
Paper. January, p. 52.
Pigler, Carmen C. 1993. RIMS Multipliers for the United States. Letter from Carmen C. Pigler,
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, Washington, D.C. to Maureen F.
Kaplan, Eastern Research Group, Inc. Lexington, MA. 1 September.
S&P. 1992. Standard & Poor's Industry Surveys: Basic analysis. Building & forest products:
includes paper. 160 (20) sec. 1. May 14.
Storat, Richard D. 1992. The U.S. pulp, paper, and paperboard industry: A profile. Paper
presented at the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency International Symposium on Pollution
Prevention in the Manufacture of Pulp and Paper. Washington, DC. August 17-19.
3-123
-------
-------
SECTION FOUR
REGULATORY ALTERNATIVES AND COMPLIANCE COSTS
Effluent guidelines and Maximum Achievable Control Technology (MACT) standards are
technology-based regulations. While the facility that is the source of discharge or emission need
not install any specific pollution control technology, the regulatory requirements must be based
on a technology that can achieve the specified limits. The Development Document and
Background Information Document detail the technology basis for effluent guidelines and
MACT standards. Section 4.1 presents a summary of the technologies considered as the basis for
regulatory requirements. Section 4.2 summarizes the compliance costs associated with the
regulatory requirements.
4.1 COMPLIANCE OPTIONS AND REGULATORY ALTERNATIVES
For the purpose of establishing effluent limitations guidelines and emission standards for
hazardous air pollutants, an industry may be subcategorized based on manufacturing process
and/or other distinguishing characteristics. The pulp, paper, and paperboard industry is divided
into 12 subcategories that incur additional pollution control requirements under this rulemaking.
Table 4-1 lists the subcategories and references the regulatory requirements for each of them.
The compliance components for a given facility, therefore, depend on which regulations are
applicable to that facility. While subcategorization is, in some cases, also appropriate for MACT
standards, the air controls for the pulp and paper industry do not vary by suboategory.
Each set of regulatory requirements (also called compliance components) includes
options, which are briefly described in Section 4.1.1. For the Best Available Technology (BAT)
and Pretreatment Standards for Existing Sources (PSES) compliance component, the options
vary by subcategory. The Clean Water Act requires effluent guidelines based on BAT to be
4-1
-------
TABLE 4-1
SUBCATEGORIES AND REGULATORY COVERAGE
Effluent Subcategory
Dissolving Kraft
Bleached Papergrade Kraft
and Soda
Unbleached Kraft
Semichemical
Dissolving Sulfite
Papergrade Sulfite
Mechanical Pulp
Non-wood Chemical
Secondary Fiber, Deink
Secondary Fiber,
Non-deink
Fine and Lightweight Papers
from Purchased Pulp
Tissue, Filter, Nonwoven, and
Paperboard from Purchased
Pulp
Number of Mills
Number of
Mills in this
Subcategory
3
88
58
21
5
11
57
12
43
342
115
169
Clean
Air Act
MACT
X
X
X
X
X
X
161
Clean Water Act
BAT&
PSES
X
X
X
X
X
X
160
BPT/
BCT
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
325
BMP
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
172
4-2
-------
economically achievable. Section Five presents the economic impacts associated with the costs
presented in Section Four.
Integrated regulatory alternatives are built by choosing an option for each of the
following compliance components:
• Wastewater Treatment Improvements (BPT or BCT)
• Best Management Practices (BMP)
• Air Controls (MACT)
• Process Changes (BAT and PSES)
The integrated regulatory alternatives developed by the Agency for this rule*naking are discussed
in Section 4.1.2.
4.1.1 Description of Compliance Components
4.1.1.1 Best Practicable Control Technology Currently Available (BPT) and Best Conventional
Pollutant Control Technology (BCT)
BPT and BCT effluent standards are for the control of conventional pollutants, including
biochemical oxygen demand (BODS), pH, total suspended solids (TSS), and oil and grease.1 The
economic considerations for effluent limitations based on BPT include a comparison of costs to
effluent reduction benefits. If the effluent limitations are based on BCT, where BCT is more
stringent than BPT, the standard must pass a two-part "cost-reasonableness" test—the cost per
pound to meet the standard cannot exceed a specific value, and the ratio of the cost of moving
from BPT to BCT to the cost of meeting BPT cannot exceed a specific value (FR, 1986). Thus,
1While the Clean Water Act does not specify that BPT be limited to conventional pollutants, the
existing BPT limitations for this industry and the proposed revised BPT limitations cover
conventional pollutants only.
4-3
-------
the economic impact analysis must examine the BPT or BCT costs separately from the costs of
the regulatory alternative.
The BCT cost test and its applicability to the proposed regulations are presented in EPA,
1993. Two technology options for conventional pollutant control are analyzed in this report;
both reflect various improvements to wastewater treatment such as additional aerators or longer
detention times for secondary treatment. For the purposes of this analysis, the costs and options
are referred to as BPT/BCT or as BPT. The actual choice of treatment improvement for
estimating costs was a site-specific judgment based on the facility's treatment in place and the
regulatory option to be met.
Two BPT/BCT options are analyzed:
• Treatment to meet the effluent performance achieved by the average of the best
performing 90 percent of the facilities (Option 1).
• Treatment to meet the effluent performance achieved by the average of the best
performing 50 percent of the facilities (Option 2).
BPT/BCT requirements' apply to all 12 subcategories.
4.1.1.2 Best Management Practices (BMP)
BMP focuses on the prevention and control of spills from pulping and chemical recovery
areas. Pulping liquors contain nonchlorinated compounds that are toxic to aquatic life, are a
source of hazardous air pollutants (e.g., methanol) and odors, and contain biological and
chemical oxygen-demanding material and color. Pulping liquor spills increase the organic and
toxic load sent to biological treatment, thereby reducing its effectiveness and efficiency.
There is only one option for BMP—they either are in place or absent. In contrast to
BPT/BCT effluent standards or BAT/PSES effluent guidelines, which do not require the
4-4
-------
installation of specific control technologies, BMP must be instituted as described in the
regulation.
BMP requirements are applicable only to the seven subcategories that produce chemical
pulps (see Table 4-1). For the purpose of evaluating economic achievability of best management
practices, BMP costs are combined with BAT/PSES costs for the subcategories with process
changes.
4.1.1.3 Maximum Achievable Control Technology (MACT)
Air emission controls consider vents, open processes, and condensate wastewaters located
in either the pulping area or the bleaching area. The requirements can include adding hoods
and vents in open process areas, routing vents to scrubbers and/or combustion devices, and steam
stripping of condensate wastewaters to remove volatile hazardous air pollutants. Table 4-2
summarizes the baseline air emission controls, the MACT floor, and more stringent options.
Shading indicates that the emission point will be controlled by the option. The control levels do
not differ by subcategory.
4.1.1.4 Best Available Technology/Process Changes (BAT and PSES)
Facilities are characterized not only by subcategory, but also by discharge status: direct
or indirect. BAT applies to direct dischargers; PSES applies to indirect dischargers. Both BAT
and PSES control nonconventional and toxic pollutants. Process changes to pulping and
bleaching operations provide the technology basis for pollution control and apply to
approximately 103 mills in four subcategories (dissolving kraft, dissolving sulfite, bleached
papergrade kraft and soda, and papergradc sulfite). Each subcategory includes several BAT and
PSES options. The subcategories and the tables describing the options are:
• Dissolving kraft (Table 4-3)
• Bleached papergrade kraft and soda (Table 4-4)
4-5
-------
TABLE 4-2
AIR CONTROL OPTIONS
Emission Point
Percent
Controlled at
Baseline
Air Control Option
Existing Sources
Floor
1
2
Pulping Area Sources Vented to a Combustion Device
Digester Blow -t- Noncondensible Gases
Digester Relief + Turpentine Recovery
Evaporator
Foam Breaker Tank
Weak Black Liquor Storage
Knotter
Washer
Decker/Screens
Oxygen Delignification
82
80
80
11
11
7
7
4
3 of 12 units
'
Bleaching Area Stages Vented to a Scrubber
1st C and D Bleach Stages
plus, 1st and 2nd
E-Stage and 2nd D-Stage
plus, 1st H-Stage
79
20
15
" '•"--: ?;•'•;•'
X
X
; X'
Wastewater Streams Steam Stripped
Evaporator "Foul" Condensate
Turpentine Decanter Condensate
Digester Blow Condensate
Evaporator "Clean" Condensate
Bleach Plant Effluent
26
22
12
0
0
"X" means option includes venting the scrubber to a combustion device.
"Foul" means >. 100 ppmw HAP and "Clean" means < 100 ppmw HAP.
4-6
-------
TABLE 4-3
PROCESS CHANGE OPTIONS FOR THE
DISSOLVING KRAFT SUBCATEGORY
Option
1
2
3
Abbreviated Description
70% C1O2
OD + 70% C1O2
OD + 100% C1O2
Description
Substitution of chlorine dioxide for
chlorine at a rate of 70%
Oxygen delignification, substitution of
chlorine dioxide for chlorine at a rate of
70%, and COD control
Oxygen delignification, complete
substitution of chlorine dioxide for
chlorine, and COD control
All options include:
Adequate wood chip size control
Eliminating dioxin precursor defoamers
Improving pulp washing
Eliminating hypochlorite
High shear mixing pulp
Enhancing extraction in bleaching (with oxygen or peroxide)
4-7
-------
TABLE 4-4
PROCESS CHANGE OPTIONS FOR THE
BLEACHED PAPERGRADE KRAFT AND SODA SUBCATEGORY
Option
1
2
3
4
5
Abbreviated Description
Split C12
70% C1O2
OD or Ext. Cook + 70%
C1O2
OD or Ext. Cook + 100%
C1O2
OD and Ext. Cook + 100%
C1O2
Description
Split addition of chlorine
Substitution of chlorine dioxide for
chlorine at a rate of 70%
Oxygen delignification or extended
delignification, substitution of chlorine
dioxide for chlorine at a rate of 70%,
and COD control
Oxygen delignification or extended
delignification, complete substitution of
chlorine dioxide for chlorine, and COD
control
Oxygen delignification and extended
cooking, complete substitution of
chlorine dioxide for chlorine, and COD
control
All options include:
Adequate wood chip size control
Eliminating dioxin precursor defoamers
Improving pulp washing
Eliminating hypochlorite
High shear mixing pulp
Enhancing extraction in bleaching (with oxygen or peroxide)
4-8
-------
• Dissolving sulfite (Table 4-5)
• Papergrade sulfite (Table 4-6)
Process changes also include closing the pulping area screen room for the control of
Chemical Oxygen Demand (COD). Screen room closure is the only process change considered
for the unbleached kraft, semichemical, and nonwood chemical subcategories.
4.1.2 Integrated Regulatory Alternatives
Seven decisions are needed to form an integrated regulatory alternative:
a Process change for dissolving kraft (BAT/PSES)
B Process change for bleached papergrade kraft and soda (BAT/PSES)
B Process change for dissolving sulfite (BAT/PSES)
m Process change for papergrade sulfite (BAT/PSES)
H Air controls for all subcategories (MACT)
• Best management practices for all subcategories (BMP)
B Wastewater treatment improvements for all subcategories (BPT)
Many combinations of these seven decisions are possible to form regulatory alternatives. Table
4-7 summarizes a subset of the regulatory alternatives to which the Agency devoted most of its
analysis.
4.2 COMPLIANCE COSTS
There are several ways to describe the costs associated with the regulation. One is the
compliance cost incurred by industry. Industry compliance cost is a measure of what the industry
would actually have to pay to comply with the regulation. As such, it amortizes the capital costs
4-9
-------
TABLE 4-5
PROCESS CHANGE OPTIONS FOR THE DISSOLVING SULFITE SUBCATEGORY
Option
1
2
Abbreviated Description
OD and 100% C1O2
TCP
Description
Oxygen delignification and complete
substitution of chlorine dioxide for
chlorine
Totally chlorine-free bleaching using
oxygen delignification, ozone and/or
peroxide
Both options include:
Adequate wood chip size control
Eliminating dioxin precursor defoamers
4-10
-------
TABLE 4-6
PROCESS CHANGE OPTIONS FOR THE PAPERGRADE SULFITE SUBCATEGORIES
Option
1
2
Abbreviated Description
OD and 100% C1O2
TCP
Description
Oxygen delignification, complete
substitution of chlorine dioxide for
chlorine, and COD control
Totally chlorine-free bleaching using
oxygen delignification or extraction
followed by peroxide, and COD control
Both options include:
Adequate wood chip size control
Eliminating dioxin precursor defoamers
Eliminating hypochlorite
4-11
-------
CA
P«<
1
5
O
z
o
s
5
u
s
Q
i S
llll
S
•s
•s
u
Air Controls
tn
a
x
U
o
P
(S
aj u
1 «
13 3
o 5
0 ^
5 >
-1
g,
•>
II
ff
~ 3 o
B5 O.T3
.3
ffl
4i
.3
n
o
.3
|
ffl
0
.S
ffl
£
^ >, ° ^
g £" &^
H p S .2
1
g
U rt- o
.0 u 8P
§5^
co Q X
GO T3
- o g 9 ^
u -a o ^
«j 2 tS jj g 2
0
r~
p o"
00
H
b
H
w d"
0 ^
81
t-H
^
1 ^^
j^ ^ 8)^
llll
1
§
T-T
O ^ a>
.£> W «"
§
-------
- -a
iill
>
«
o>
>
ol
5
Z
1
o
U
a.
8
a,
8
I
g
to
on
11
be
b
b
f-f
Q
Q ffi
Q ffi
_ cu
HI
sin
.8 o S
P5 &.T3
^ a
w- 2 S
S S « *
55 B
Q
O
8,
gi. -
,2 o S
CM W4 "O
a,
8
r to
tion
Du
scr
o
f-
R
8.8
QQ
o a
88
§8
^ ^
2
.2 "3
O M
2LS
B
w (5
a
M (B
BQ B.
§1
w o
§1
"
0
§§
O
Q
o
Qg
OO
g
§§
ao
o D
O S
4-13
-------
.. 3
» s
a
Bleach Area
Vents
s »
J'
Q (A
E
If a
S.S
£l
S
_j o
w 8P
Q
O
2 "S.
SP-S
Q O
00
OD
B
O vg
8S
t-
-------
over the equipment lifetime, includes the cost of money used to purchase the equipment,
includes the annual cost of operating and maintaining the equipment, and considers tax savings
via depreciation and higher operating costs. The industry compliance cost is sometimes called
the private cost. (See Section 3.1.1 for a more detailed description of calculating annualized
costs.) If a business can reduce the taxes it owes by depreciation, however, the federal
government bears the cost of the lost tax revenues. The business can raise its prices to recover
the cost of additional pollution control; higher prices become a cost to consumers. A second
cost, the social cost of the regulation, considers these and other types of costs due to the
regulation. Social cost is discussed in more detail in Section 4.2.2. Throughout this section, all
costs are reported in terms of 1991 dollars.
4.2.1 Industry Compliance Costs
Industry compliance costs are calculated by summing the annualized cost for a given
option or regulatory alternative over all affected facilities. Since the industry compliance cost
reflects what the business would actually have to pay to meet the increased pollution
requirements, it is an appropriate measure with which to evaluate economic impacts. Due to the
requirement to evaluate economic achievability of effluent guidelines and standards, industry
compliance costs are examined separately for BPT/BCT, BAT/PSES, and the integrated
regulatory alternatives. Costs associated with BMP are assigned to BAT/PSES costs for
subcategories affected by process changes. Impacts associated with the regulatory costs are
summarized in Section Five.
4.2.1.1 BPT Costs
Table 4-8 summarizes capital, operating and maintenance (o&m), and annualized costs
for incremental BPT control. BPT requirements are applicable to approximately 325 mills. The
annualized industry compliance costs are $45 million for Option 1 and $65 million for Option 2.
4-15
-------
TABLE 4-8
SUMMARY OF BPT COSTS
THOUSANDS OF 1991 DOLLARS
1
2
CAPITAL COST
$202,409
$336.641
O&M EXPENSE
$44,342
$59,400
ANNUALIZED COST
$44.590
$65,409
Notes: Factor for Converting $1989 to $1991:
The annualized costs include cost savings that may be
generated at some mills.
The costs above include BPT costs for all mills.
BPT Is applicable to 325 mills.
S:\ECON\PULP2\EIA\SEC_4\TABL48.WK3
1.0477
4-16
-------
4.2.1.2 Process Change Costs (BAT/PSES)
Costs considered under BAT/PSES include the costs for process change, best
management practices, COD control, and wastewater treatment for indirect dischargers, as
appropriate. BAT/PSES costs are summarized by subcategory in Tables 4-9 through 4-13.
The annualized compliance costs for dissolving kraft mills range from $2 million to $15
million, depending on the option (Table 4-9). The annualized cost for Option 2 is $11.9 million.
For dissolving sulfite, the annualized compliance costs range from $5 million to $15 million
(Table 4-10). For bleached papergrade kraft and soda, the annualized costs range from $122
million to $641 million (Table 4-11). For Option 4, the cost is $303 million. For papergrade
sulfite, the annualized costs range from $27 million to $46 million (Table 4-12).
There are 22 mills in the unbleached kraft subcategory that have production in one of the
first four subcategories (dissolving kraft, dissolving sulfite, bleached papergrade kraft and soda,
and papergrade sulfite). To avoid double-counting the BMP and COD control costs, the mills
are not included in the costs shown in Table 4-13. The annualized compliance cost for the
remaining 36 mills is $6 million.
There are two mills in the semichemical subcategory that also have production in one of
the four subcategories listed above. All process change, BMP, and COD control costs for those
mills already have been included in the other subcategory. They are not included in the costs for
the semichemical subcategory to avoid double-counting. The annualized compliance cost for the
remaining 19 mills is $7 million (Table 4-13).
Table 4-13 also summarizes the cost for BMP for the nonwood chemical pulping
subcategory. The annualized compliance cost for the 12 mills is $336 thousand.
4-17
-------
TABLE 4-9
SUMMARY OF COSTS BY SUBCATEGORY : DISSOLVING KRAFT
THOUSANDS OF 1991 DOLLARS
CAPITAL COST O&M EXPENSE ANNUALIZED COST
1
2
3
$65,839
$138,784
$143,937
($8,457)
($2,489)
$1 ,653
$1,726
$11,900
$14,711
Notes: Factor for Converting $1989 to $1991: 1.0477
The annualized costs include cost savings that may be generated at some mills.
There are 3 mills in the dissolving kraft subcategory.
TABLE 4-10
SUMMARY OF COSTS BY SUBCATEGORY : DISSOLVING SULFITE
THOUSANDS OF 1991 DOLLARS
OPTION
1
2
CAPITAL COST
$110,051
$86,859
O&M EXPENSE ANNUALIZED COST
($5,141) $4,943
$14,936 $14,829
Notes: Factor for Converting $1989 to $1991:
The annualized costs include cost savings that may be
generated at some mills.
There are 5 mills in this subcategory.
B:\TABL49.WK4
1.0477
4-18
-------
TABLE 4-11
SUMMARY OF COSTS BY SUBCATEGORY : BLEACHED PAPERGRADE KRAFT
THOUSANDS OF 1991 DOLLARS
OPTION CAPITAL COST O&M EXPENSE ANNUALIZED COST
1 $815,009
2 $1,253.170
3 $2,162,296
4 $2,300,850
5 $4,899,088
$80,628
$40,858
$61,289
$152,665
$315,512
$122,172
$139,694
$237,193
$302,571
$640,576
Notes: Factor for Converting $1989 to $1991: 1.0477
The annualized costs include cost savings that may be generated at some mills.
There are 88 mills in the bleached papergrade kraft subcategory;
BAT/PSES applies to 87 mills.
TABLE 4-12
SUMMARY OF COSTS BY SUBCATEGORY : PAPERGRADE SULFITE
THOUSANDS OF 1991 DOLLARS
OPTION
CAPITAL COST
$279,290
$115,408
O&M EXPENSE
$32,844
$26,547
ANNUALIZED COST
$46,216
$26,726
Notes: Factor for Converting $1989 to $1991: 1.0477
The annualized costs include cost savings that may be generated
at some mills.
There are 11 mills in this subcategory.
S:\ECON\PULP2\EIA\SEC_4\TABL411 .WK4
4-19
-------
TABLE 4-13
SUMMARY OF COSTS FOR THREE SUBCATEGORIES :
UNBLEACHED KRAFT, SEMICHEMICAL, AND NONWOOD CHEMICAL
THOUSANDS OF 1991 DOLLARS
SUBCATEGORY CAPITAL COST O&M EXPENSE ANNUALIZED COST
Unbleached Kraft
Sernlchemlcal
Norwood Chemcal
$99,122
$43.928
$3,000
($6.307)
$5.389
$120
$6.004
$7,149
$336
Notes: Factor for Converting $1989 to $1991: 1.0477
The annualized costs include cost savings that may be generated at some mills.
There are 58 mills in the unbleached papergrade kraft subcategory; costs for 22 mills
are counted in another subcategory
There are 21 mills in the semichemical subcategory; 2 mills whose costs are
counted in another subcategory.
There are 12 mills in the nonwood chemical subcategory.
S:\ECON\PULP2\EIA\SEC_4\TABL413.WK3
4-20
-------
43.1.3 Integrated Regulatory Alternative Costs
Table 4-14 summarizes the capital, o&m, and annualized cost for the regulatory
alternatives. The annualized industry compliance costs range from $173 million to $657 million,
with Alternative 26 costing $592 million. In the industry profile, Table 2-27 lists the expenditures
on environmental protection for 1988 to 1990 as $572 million to $1.3 billion per year. These
constituted between 11 to 16 percent of the total expenditures for new plants and equipment for
the 1988 to 1990 period. The annualized costs for the regulatory alternatives, then, are within
the range of the expenditures seen in recent years. In 1989, the capital investment in the
industry totaled about $68 billion (Table 2-26). Capital investment for the regulatory alternatives
ranged from $775 million to $4.3 billion, or from about 1 to 6 percent of the existing investment
at the end of 1989. Capital expenditures for Alternative 26, for example, are $3.9 billion, or
about one-half the expenditures for 1990 (Table 2-27).
Table 4-15 summarizes the BAT/PSES and BPT costs as a percentage of the total cost for
the regulatory alternatives. The process change costs form between 51 and 62 percent of the cost
of the regulatory alternative. BPT costs form an additional 10 to 12 percent of the regulatory
cost.
4.2.2 Approximations of Social Cost
One way of evaluating the merit and efficiency of social decisions, like the one to
internalize the ill effects of pollution on human health and the environment through regulation,
is to compare the social costs of regulation to the social benefits. The social costs of regulation
are the opportunity costs borne by society for employing our scarce resources in pursuit of
pollution control. The social .costs of the pulp and paper regulations have been estimated two
ways. The most theoretically complete way uses various results from the market impact model to
estimate social costs. The less burdensome way uses the engineering estimate of control costs,
but this estimate is a second-best approximation.
4-21
-------
TABLE 4-14
SUMMARY OF POLLUTION CONTROL COSTS ASSOCIATED WITH
REGULATORY ALTERNATIVES
(THOUSANDS OF 1991 DOLLARS)
Regulatory
Alternative
2
3
4
5
11
16
17
18
22
23
24
25
26
Capital Cost
$775,481
$779,559
$884,787
$1.161.872
$3,708,235
$3,742,111
$3,847,339
$4,126,487
$3,846,775
$3,880,651
$3,985,879
$4,265.027
$3,903,850
O&M Expense Annualized Cost
$174,370
$174,618
$186,972
$208,907
$322,353
$324,414
$336,767
$358,417
$413,723
$415,784
$428,137
$449.787
$395,708
$173,494
$173,960
$190,842
$229,365
$531.706
$536,092
$552,974
$591,619
$597,078
$601,465
$618,346
$656,991
$591,580
343 mills were analyzed to calculate pollution control costs of regulatory alternatives.
S:\ECON\PULP2\EIA\SEC_4\TABL414.WK3
4-22
-------
5.
2 si
*fl
P CL.
O
= E,
s a
II -
F iu
£•§
il
CMCMCM-r-t-i-'-O'-
..
tAlAiAtOCDCDC
oqcqoqoqcviCHNOJco
concocoGioioiaiai
OOOOCOCDCDCOU)
CO CO CO CO CO CO CO CO CO
opppoooop
SSSSSSS5SS
CNCNCMCNC
cocococoooooo
c^c^cgcNcocoeoeoco
v*-v*****v»t***v>**
cooqoqaqcqcqoqeqO)
^r V ^ V •**' ** ^ ^ ^
S
i
I
i
o
W
to
4-23
-------
4.22.1 Market Model Social Cost Estimates
The social costs of regulation include both monetary and nonmonetary outlays made by
society. Monetary outlays include private-sector compliance costs, government administrative
costs, and various adjustment costs. Non-monetary outlays that are often assigned a monetary
value include losses in consumers' or producers' surpluses in product markets, discomfort or
inconvenience, loss of time, and slowing the rate of innovation.
Table 4-16 shows the estimates of social cost derived from the market impact model for
the integrated Regulatory Alternatives 3,16, 23, 24, 25, and 26. Alternatives 3,16, 23, and 26
contain the MACT floor level of air add-on control with increasingly stringent process
modification requirements. Alternatives 24 and 25 contain increasingly stringent air add-on
controls on top of the process modification options selected for Alternative 23. The estimates
include producer surplus loss, consumer surplus loss, annualized worker dislocation costs, and
government and private administrative costs.
In a market environment, consumers and producers of pulp and paper products derive
welfare from market transactions. The difference between the maximum price consumers are
willing to pay for pulp and paper products and the price they actually pay is referred to as
consumer surplus. Similarly, the difference between the minimum price producers are willing to
accept for pulp and paper products and the price they actually receive is referred to as producer
surplus. Because equilibrium prices and quantities change in each market affected by pulp and
paper regulations, there are corresponding changes in consumer and producer surplus.
Worker dislocation costs are estimated based on incremental willingness-to-pay measures
for job dislocations in a hedonic wage framework. This estimate conceptually approximates the
onetime willingness to pay to avoid an involuntary unemployment episode. Theoretically, the
estimate includes all worker-borne costs net of any off-setting pecuniary or nonpecuniary
"benefits" of unemployment (e.g., unemployment compensation, leisure time enjoyment). The
hedonic displacement cost estimate is a net present value valuation. For the paper and allied
products sector, the implied one-time statistical cost (expressed as a net present value) of an
involuntary layoff is $67,323 (1991 dollars). This value is multiplied by the total number of
4-24
-------
TABLE 4-16
ANNUAL SOCIAL COST ESTIMATES: MARKET MODEL
(MILLIONS OF 1991 DOLLARS)
Social Cost Category
Consumer Surplus Loss
Producer Surplus Loss
Worker Displacement
Costs
Government & Private
Administrative Costs
(MACT only)
Total Social Cost
Alt. 3
161.4
114.9
4.7
2.5
283.5
Alt 16
493.2
301.0
24.3
2.5
820.9
Alt. 23
497.7
403.7
24.6
2.5
928.5
Alt. 24
499.0
428.0
24.6
2.5
954.2
Alt. 25
499.2
483.5
24.7
2.5
1,010.0
Alt. 26
477.2
415.7
24.6
2.5
920.1
4-25
-------
displaced workers estimated by the market impact model to calculate the net present value of the
worker displacement cost. This cost is then annualized. For Regulatory Alternative 26, worker
displacement costs are estimated at $24.6 million.
Government administrative costs include the cost to federal and state governments to
review facility compliance reports and otherwise ensure and oversee compliance with the
proposed standards. An estimate of these costs is not available at the time of this publication.
The annual social cost for Regulatory Alternative 26 is approximately $920 million.
4.22.2 Social Cost Estimates Using Engineering Costs
The social cost of the regulation can be approximated by the pretax annual engineering
cost. The capital cost of the rule (TCI) is annualized over its expected life (15 years) at the
OMB-approved social discount rate (10 percent at the time of this writing). The annual o&m is
then added to the annualized capital cost to arrive at the total annual social cost approximation.
Table 4-17 shows the estimates of social cost derived with this method for Regulatory
Alternatives 3, 16, 23, 24, 25, and 26. The social cost, using engineering costs, for Regulatory
Alternative 26 is estimated at $909 million.
43 REFERENCES
FR. 1986. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 40 CFR Parts 405 et al. Best conventional
pollutant control technology; effluents limitations guidelines; final rule. Federal Register.
51(131):24974-25002. July 9.
EPA. 1993. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. BCT cost test for the proposed effluent
limitations for the pulp, paper, and papcrboard industry. Washington, DC: EPA Office of
Water.
4-26
-------
TABLE 4-17
ANNUAL SOCIAL COST ESTIMATES: ENGINEERING COST
(MILLIONS OF 1991 DOLLARS)
Engineering Cost
Category
Total Capital
Investment
Annual O&M
Total Social Cost
Approximation
Alt. 3
779.6
174.6
277.1
Alt. 16
3,708.2
324.4
811.9
Alt. 23
3,880.7
415.8
926.0
Alt. 24
3,985.9
428.1
952.1
Alt. 25
4,265.0
449.8
1,010.5
Alt. 26
3,903.9
395.7
909.0
4-27
-------
-------
SECTION FIVE
ECONOMIC IMPACTS
The costs associated with incremental pollution control are discussed in Section Four.
The impacts of these costs were evaluated with the financial and market models presented in
Section Three. The impacts estimated by the financial impact model are given in Section 5.1, the
impacts projected by the market model are given in Section 5.2, and a comparison of results
from both models is discussed in Section 5.3. The analysis focuses on facilities that are estimated
to incur costs to comply with the regulation. Of the estimated 565 pulp, paper, and paperboard
facilities in the United States, the proposed regulations are applicable to approximately 343
facilities. Of these, about 300 facilities are anticipated to incur costs; about 265 facilities—nearly
half—are anticipated to incur no costs.
5.1 FINANCIAL IMPACT ANALYSIS RESULTS
5.1.1 Closure Analysis
If the present value of the future earnings for a facility after the imposition of
incremental pollution control costs is less than the salvage value of the facility, the facility is
projected to close. (Section 3.2.1 discusses the methods used for estimating future earnings and
salvage value.) The closure analysis is conducted for each facility under several cost
scenarios—under each regulatory alternative; under BAT/PSES requirements (if appropriate);
and under costs for wastewater treatment upgrades (BPT costs).
5.1.1.1 Closures Due to BPT Costs
There are 325 facilities to which BPT is applicable and for which wastewater treatment
upgrade costs were estimated. Some of these mills will not have to upgrade their equipment to
meet the new limitations; these mills are assigned $0 costs (see Table 4-8 for total BPT costs).
5-1
-------
Of these, 223 are in the closure analysis.1 One facility closes under BPT Option 1, where the
facility must meet the effluent treatment performance obtained by the best performing 90
percent of the subcategory. Three facilities close under BPT Option 2, where the facility must
meet the effluent treatment performance obtained by the best performing 50 percent of the
subcategory. These impacts are summarized with additional information in Section 5.1.2.1.
5.1.7.2 Closures Due To BAT/PSES and BMP Costs
Process change descriptions are given by subcategory in Tables 4-3 through 4-6. Costs
are given by subcategory in Tables 4-9 through 4-13. Impacts associated with facility closure are
shown by subcategory in Section 5.1.2.2 tables.
Dissolving Kraft: There are three facilities in this subcategory. There are no closures
under any of the process change costs shown in Table 4-9.
Dissolving Sulfite; There are five facilities in this subcategory; four are included in the
closure analysis. One mill is projected to close under Option 1 (oxygen delignification and 100%
chlorine dioxide substitution). Two mills are projected to close under the TCP (totally chlorine
free) option.
Bleached Papergrade Kraft and Soda: There are 88 facilities in this subcategory; 75 are
in the closure analysis. There are two closures projected with Option 1 (split addition of
chlorine) and Option 2 (70% substitution); three closures projected with Option 3 and Option 4
(oxygen delignification or extended cooking with 70% or 100% chlorine dioxide substitution,
respectively); and nine closures projected with Option 5 (oxygen delignification and extended
cooking with 100% chlorine dioxide substitution).
'A facility can be excluded from the closure analysis for several reasons: it may be too new to
be in the data base (i.e., it went into operation after 1989), there may be insufficient data held at
the facility level to perform the analysis, or it may be a baseline closure.
5-2
-------
Papergrade Sulfite: There are 11 facilities in this subcaiegory; 10 are in the closure
analysis. There are five closures projected with Option 1 (oxygen delignification and 100%
chlorine dioxide substitution) and three projected with Option 2 (TCP).
Unbleached Kraft, Semichemieal. and Nonwood Chemical: There is only one option for
each subcategory. There are no closures projected with the option for each of these
subcategories.
5.1.1.3 Closures Due to Regulatory Alternative Costs
The regulatory alternatives are described in Table 4-7 and the costs are listed in Table
4-14. There are 343 facilities for which costs under this rulemaking were estimated; the closure
analysis examined 237 facilities. There are three closures projected with Alternatives 2 through
5. Fourteen closures are projected with Alternatives 11 through 23. Fifteen closures are
projected for Alternatives 24 and 25. Thirteen closures, the lowest number for an alternative
involving process changes, are projected for Alternative 26.
5.1.2 Additional Economic Impacts
As explained in Section 3.2, the financial model projects losses in shipments, exports, and
jobs associated with facility closure. These impacts are summarized by subcategory and by
option. This section presents the impacts associated with the closures summarized in Section
5.1.1. In some cases, certain results are not reported in the summary tables because data
aggregation is inadequate to protect confidential business information. These results are
identified by "ND" (not disclosed) entries in the table. For comparison, the industry-wide totals
for the number of mills, shipments (tonnage and value), exports, and jobs are given in the left-
5-3
-------
hand column in each table.2 All dollar values shown in Tables 5-1 through 5-6 are in terms of
1989 dollars, as in the industry profile (Section Two).
5.1.2.1 Impacts Associated with BPT Costs
The costs associated with BPT Option 1 lead to a single closure among all facilities
analyzed, leading to an estimated $13 million loss in shipments (of which $1 million is exports),
and about 100 jobs (Table 5-1). Option 2 results in three closures that lead to a $217 million
loss in shipments, and about 1,100 jobs.
5.12.2 Impacts Associated with BAT/PSES Costs
Dissolving Kraft: There are no closures caused by any of the pollution control options
considered for the dissolving kraft subcategory. Hence, there are no associated impacts.
Dissolving Sulfite: The costs associated with implementing Option 1 (oxygen
delignification and 100 percent chlorine dioxide substitution) lead to a single projected mill
closure for this subcategory (Table 5-2). The impacts with these closures are not reported in
Table 5-2 to protect confidential data. The costs associated with implementing Option 2 (TCP)
lead to two mill closures. For perspective, the loss in shipments is less than 0.5 percent of total
industry shipments and about 3 percent of total exports.
Bleached Papergrade Kraft and Soda: Table 5-3 lists the closures and impacts associated
with the pollution control options analyzed for the bleached papergrade kraft and soda
subcategory. The impacts fall into three groups: Option I/Option 2 (two closures); Option
3/Option 4 (three closures); and Option 5 (nine closures). The impacts associated with Options
•The industry totals reflect all facilities that could be categorized for the regulatory flexibility
analysis. The totals for shipments and exports may be slightly smaller than those given in Section
Two because a small number of mills had zero employees (i.e., contract labor) or did not state the
number of employees.
5-4
-------
TABLE 5-1
IMPACTS ASSOCIATED WITH
BPT COSTS
1989 DATA
Industry Total
Option 1
Option 2
Number of Mills
Closures
565
Number of Employees
Loss in Employees*
220,491
100
1,100
Shipment (Tons)
Loss in Shipment Tonnage
86,711,752
5,752
266,240
Shipments ($000)
Loss in Shipments ($000)
$58,529,186
$13,026
$216,612
Exports ($000)
Loss in Exports ($000)
$5,853,950
$966
$1,599
Rounded to nearest 100 employees.
5-5
-------
TABLE 5-2
IMPACTS ASSOCIATED WITH
BAT/PSES COSTS: DISSOLVING SULFITE
1989 DATA
Industry Total
Option 1
Option 2
Number of Mills
Closures
565
Number of Employees
Loss in Employees
220,491
ND
ND
Shipments (Tons)
Loss in Shipment Tonnage
86,711,752
ND
ND
Shipments ($000)
Loss in Shipments ($000)
$58.529.186
ND
ND
Export ($000)
Loss in Exports ($000)
$5.853,950
ND
ND
5-6
-------
TABLE 5-3
IMPACTS ASSOCIATED WITH
BAT/PSES COSTS: BLEACHED PAPERGRADE KRAFT AND SODA
1989 DATA
Industry Total
Option 1 Option 2 Option 3
Option 4
Options
Number of Mills
565
Number of Employees
220,491
Shipments (Tons)
86,711,752
Shipments ($000)
$58,529,186
Export ($000)
$5,853,950
Closures
234
Loss in Employees*
3,700 5,100 5.800
Loss in Shipment Tonnage
757.133 1,083,421 1,393,607
Loss in Shipment ($000)
$853,719 $1,146.540 $1,360,066
Loss in Exports ($000)
$1.262 $2.679 $81.204
4
5,800
1,393,607
$1,360,066
$81^04
9
12,700
3.685,380
$3,271.996
$264,234
Rounded to nearest 100 employees.
5-7
-------
3 and 4 include a loss of about 5,800 jobs and $1.4 billion in shipments, representing about 2.5
percent of current production levels in the industry. Less than 6 percent of the shipments
projected to be lost under Options 3 and 4 are exports. Moving from Option 4 to Option 5
nearly triples the impacts in terms of closures, employment, shipments, and exports. Projected
impacts under Option 5 include losses of more than 5.5 percent of total industry production
($3.27 billion).
Papergrade Sulfite: The impacts for the papergrade sulfite category are summarized in
Table 5-4. For the papergrade sulfite subcategory, there are five closures under Option 1
(oxygen delignification and 100 percent chlorine dioxide substitution). Under Option 1, there are
3,900 jobs projected to be lost along with over $766 million in shipments, $3.6 million of which
constitutes export sales. Under Option 2 (TCP), losses are projected at 2,600 jobs and $475
million in shipments, including $1.4 million in exports. For this subcategory, a totally chlorine-
free process (Option 2) is associated with smaller impacts (e.g., 1,200 fewer jobs lost and 40
percent lower loss in the value of shipments and exports) than an elemental-chlorine-free
production process (Option 1).
Unbleached Kraft, Semichemical, and Nonwood Chemical: There are no closures
l
associated with best management practices, COD control, and wastewater treatment for indirect
dischargers (where applicable) for these subcategories. Hence, there are no associated impacts.
5.7.2.3 Impacts Associated with Regulatory Alternative Costs
Table 5-5 summarizes the impacts associated with the regulatory alternative costs. The
impacts fall into three groups:
• Alternatives 2 through 5 (3 closures)
• Alternatives 11 through 23 (14 closures)3
3Thc alternatives analyzed in this report are not numbered sequentially. For example, there are
no Alternatives 6 through 9.
5-8
-------
TABLE 5-4
IMPACTS ASSOCIATED WITH
BAT/PSES COSTS: PAPERGRADE SULFITE
1989 DATA
Industry Total
Option 1
Option 2
Number of Mills
Closures
565
Number of Employees
Loss in Employees*
220,491
3,900
2,600
Shipments (Tons)
Loss in Shipment Tonnage
86,711,752
791,600
506,535
Loss in Shipments ($OOOT
Shipments ($000)
$58,529,186
$766,791
$475,372
Export ($000)
Loss in Exports ($000)
$5,853,950
$3,612
$1,405
Rounded to nearest 100 employees.
5-9
-------
TABLE 5-6
IMPACTS ASSOCIATED WITH
INTEGRATED ALTERNATIVE COSTS
10BS DATA
Industry Total
Alternatives
2 Through 5
AHomatlvos
11 Through 23
AKomouvBt
24 Through 25
Atterrauv*
26
Number of Mats
565
Number of Employees
220.491
Shipments (Tons)
86.711,752
Shipments ($000)
$58.529.186
EXDOrt (JOOO)
$5,853.950
3 '
1.900
736.104
$459.700
$2.207
Closures
14
Loss In Employees*
11.100
Loss In Shipments (tons)
3.029.161
Loss In Shipments ($000)
$2,543,508
Loss In Exports ($000)
$285,658
15
12,500
3,590,501
$2.937.776
$371,528
13
10,700
2,869,346
$2,426,580
$191.784
Roundod to nearest 100 employees.
5-10
-------
• Alternatives 24 and 25 (15 closures)
• Alternative 26 (13 closures)
Alternative 26 has the smallest amount of impacts for an alternative with process changes. The
impacts include approximately 10,700 jobs lost. Losses associated with the 13 closures include
2.9 million tons of pulp, paper, and paperboard (worth $2.4 billion dollars), including $192
million in exports. This is approximately 5 percent of the jobs, 3 to 4 percent of the shipments
(tonnage and value), and 3 percent of the exports associated with the pulp, paper, and
paperboard industry. The reader should keep in mind that the financial model includes several
conservative assumptions such as no cost pass-through (i.e., the facility cannot raise prices to
recoup increased costs), no growth, no additional revenue sources for the facilities included in
the estimate of earnings, and the use of net income (rather than cash flow) to project future
earnings (see Section 3.2 for details). The estimated impacts presented in Section 5.1 are likely
to represent upper-bound estimates.
Total impacts on employment and output, both direct and indirect, are estimated with
final-demand national-level input-output multipliers from the U.S. Department of Commerce's
Regional Input-Output Modeling System (RIMS II; Pigler 1993; see Section 3.2.3.2, Table 3-16).
Beginning with the $2.4 billion dollars in lost shipments estimated for Alternative 26, Table 5-6
subdivides these losses into pulp, paper, and paperboard. The top half of Table 5-6 uses the
final-demand multiplier for employment for each category to estimate total employment losses
associated with Alternative 26. The estimated 67,100 jobs lost is inclusive of direct jobs lost; that
is, the 10,700 jobs lost shown in Table 5-5 should not be added to this figure. For perspective,
this is approximately one-tenth of 1 percent of the estimated 90.5 million people employed in the
private sector in the United States during 1989 (DOL, 1992.) Table 5-6 also includes an estimate
of the total loss in output associated with Alternative 26. The final-demand multiplier for output
represents the total dollar change in output for each dollar change in industry output. The $2.4
billion loss in shipments due to projected facility closures ripples through the economy to become
an estimated $8 billion loss in output. For comparison, the 1989 gross domestic product was
$5,251 billion (CEA, 1993). The loss is approximately two-tenths of 1 percent of the gross
domestic product for 1989.
5-11
-------
TABLE 5-6
TOTAL OUTPUT IMPACTS OF LOSS OF
SHIPMENTS IN PULP, PAPER, AND PAPERBOARD INDUSTRY
BASED ON CLOSURES FROM ALTERNATIVE 26
Production Category
Loss In Shipments ($000. 1989)
RIMS II Employment Multiplier
Total Employment Loss
RIMS II Output Multiplier
Total Output Impacts ($000,1989)
Pulp
$343,288
29.7
10,196
$4
$1,207.790
Paper
$1,889.829
27.2
51,403
3.2303
$6,104.715
Paperboard
$193,463
28.2
5,456
3.3589
$649,823
Total
$2,426,580
67,055
$7,962,328
* Employment multiplier represents the amount of jobs lost for every $1,000,000 reduction in output.
Source: Pigler, 1993.
5-12
-------
The loss in federal and state revenues was also estimated for the regulatory alternatives
(Table 5-7). This is the difference in the annualized cost before and after tax shields are
considered (see Section 3.23.3 for details). The revenues that the industry saves by reducing its
taxes result in revenue losses to the federal and state governments. The values presented in
Table 5-7 represent the annualized value of these lost tax revenues over the 16-year period
during which the equipment is purchased, installed, depreciated, and operated. The annualized
losses include not only the loss of the tax revenues but also the interest that these revenues could
have earned during this period. The loss to the federal and state governments is about $233 to
$299 million per year for Alternatives 11 through 26. The loss associated with Alternative 26 is
$268 million per year.
The national average state tax rate of 6.75 percent is used in the cost annualization model
in conjunction with a 34 percent federal tax rate (see Section 3.1). The loss in state revenues,
therefore, ranges from $38 to $50 million per year. This loss, in turn, is distributed among the 42
states with pulp and paper operations (see Section 2.4).
Table 5-8 presents a summary of the results from the facility-level financial ratio analysis.
The left-hand side of the table lists the baseline values for 1985, 1988, and 1989. These years
indicate recent low and high points in the business cycle. The percent variation from the
maximum to minimum values for those three years is shown in the next column. The percent
variation provides a measure of the fluctuation in financial ratios due to the business cycle. As
discussed in Section 3.2.2, the regulatory costs are added to the 1989 financial data and the ratios
are recalculated. The post-regulatory ratios are presented in the remainder of Table 5-8. The
results shown in Table 5-8 are the average (calculated as the arithmetic mean) and median
change in gross income margin, return on assets, and current ratio. The calculation and
interpretation of each ratio is discussed in Section 3.2.2. For net working capital and net
working capital-to-total assets, the results are reported as the change in the mean and median
values. As anticipated, the mean values show greater fluctuations. This is because the mean is
sensitive to a few outlying values. The median values are more stable and are more indicative of
what happens to a "typical" mill. Most of the impacts are within the range seen in the business
cycle. The exceptions are the ratios that involve net working capital. The changes in net
working capital appear to extend beyond the envelope defined by the business cycle, but this may
5-13
-------
TABLE 6-7
LOSS IN FEDERAL AND STATE REVENUES
FROM REGULATORY ALTERNATIVES
Regulatory
Alternative
2
3
4
5
11
16
17
18
22
23
24
25
26
Annualized Loss in
Federal and State Revenues
($000.1991)
$91,057
$91,268
$99,140
$115,693
$232,962
$234.743
$242,615
$259,120
$273,003
$274,783
$282.656
$299,160
$267,541
5-14
-------
CO
03
3
0
1
3!
o
ul
ui
ST* CO
is
? 5?!
13
S
3
5
8
S
3
5
5
o
i
!*
i
jg
i ^z
Is
JlO
i 2
u
5
i
. m
*
|
CM
5
i
"I
5
- T™
|
r
k
^
i
i
8* efi iSlS
55 i?
(O CO CO CO
tO CNJ OJ hj"
## **
•*• CO •* CN
to' oJ °* **V
"7
#ae #*
to' CNl" CN t^
CN CN O O
CD 04 CM N-*
~ i ^ i
O* CN CO CM
CO O* CM IY
O *~ CO O">
tn oj T- to'
CO O>
-79 ^
T?
in i r^ *- o
•»- T- CO o> in N;
cq K r-.
•Pf" S???
seaR *#
co tn o> r-;
CO ^ CO CO
OJ « N; N;
CO *f CO CO
~ ' CNI OJ
T— CO CO CO
' ' O^l CNI
h. ^ -^ CO
r^ V to' oi
"1 01 CSI
in -^ to m
r-^ ^ in ^
1 ' OJ OJ
m co ^ in
i^ ^j in *-
1 ' OJ OJ
aese aea?
O) CO v_ O
-«• o
OJ Cp CO CO
aR S^ aR a^
to o> -^ p
OJ 9 CO CO
co to to cq
CO tO OJ (O
O> ^ CO O>
«- f»- CO CO
CM »- "**.'°.
S3
to to to V
co to in co
OJ ^ 0} «
•* to to r*.
in ^-. Of*-.
1M *- «? ">.
CO 1 CSI
cq cq
^«?
*»e
O> CO
5"?
gege
??
U> v;
CM OJ
m co,
OJOJ
CO CO
55
o *-'
OJ OJ
CO •«-
c> *-
OJ O^
a«»?
in N.
19 to'
asa?
CO CD
"T *9
# #
o> in
-------
indicate that the facility must use sources of money beyond working capital to finance the
pollution control equipment.
Table 5-9 presents a summary of the results of the company-level financial ratio analysis.
The complete balance sheets and income statements available at this level of the corporate
hierarchy make it possible to include debt-to-asset and times-interest-earned ratios in the
i
analysis. The debt-to-asset ratio is used to determine to what degree assets of a company are
financed through debt. The times-interest-earned ratio examines the ratio of cash flow to
interest payments to determine how much additional interest burden a company can absorb. For
net income margin, return on assets, times-interest-earned, and net working capital ratios, the
changes induced by the cost of the regulatory alternatives are within the same range seen in the
business cycle. For the current ratio, debt-to-assets, and net working capital-to-total assets ratios,
i
the means lie slightly beyond the range set by the business cycle, but the medians are within the
range. This is attributable to the fact that closures may result in'significant variations in the
financial ratios. These outliers tend to skew the mean while only slightly affecting the median.
For example, when a company with poor financial ratios suffers a worsening of financial
condition, it remains in the lower half of the company population. The company(ies) in the 50th
percentile stay in the 50th percentile with their previous financial ratios; there is merely a
reordering of rank among the lower-ranked companies.
5.2 MARKET MODEL IMPACT RESULTS
Results for the market impact model were generated for all the integrated regulatory
alternatives that were considered by the Agency as the potential basis for the proposed standards.
This section presents the market impact model results for six alternatives: Alternatives 3, 16, 23,
24. 25. and 26. Alternatives 3, 16, 23, and 26 include the MACT floor options, with varying
levels of process modification option stringency. Alternative 3 does not employ any process
modification options. Alternatives 24 and 25 employ MACT options more stringent than the
floor with the process modification options of Alternative 23. The results for the six integrated
alternatives from the market impact model are anticipated to span the range of impact severity of
all evaluated alternatives.
5-16
-------
i
CO
CO
^
<
5
O
I
•
5
5
I
TABLE 5-9
COMPANY-LEVEL FIN
ALL COMPANIES
NS
!
5
S
X
3
8
*f *
1
f S
s *
™
f5
C
» 5
to 4
1 ;
§ *
|;
r
E
u
a
'
«
c
4
c
:
*-
i
i
i
fc
a
• >
g!
5 i
m
•
CM tO
to o>
!•* CO
O CO
T
**
CM CO
O CO
CM CO
0,0
1
CM h-
O CO
50 •*
C3 CO
o> ^r
o •*
9 «7
jP jp
in o
CM 0
CO O
CMO
^- O
CM 0
«- O
CM O
O CO
to W
CO CO
5 to
in in
_
to o
to to
CM v-
CM ^
C C
Ratio
Net Income Margin:
Mea
Media
if**
•ir- CO
m co
T^
^^
CO O
of h-
T
aea*
T- CO
#,^
? *?
1
CM CO
^•9
ay CM
CO tip
#*
CO CO
s«a«
CO CO
*Ji ^o
CM 0
CO O
CO O
CMO
CO O
CM O
a«ae
to o
CM O
CO O>
CM CT>
CO CO
O CO
N- h^
^P OS
•^- o>
CO CO
r»- co
in in
c b'
Return on Assets'
Mea
Media
^- CM
CM Y
m CM
CM if
seae
^- CM
CM TJ-
<^ae
•^ CM
C>l Y
•«*• CM
CM •»-
^r CM
CM *r-
CO CM
CM T^-
CO CM
«»T
CO CM
^ T
^0 ^o
in o
9°
#*
•*r o
-
CM T-
c b
Current Ratio
Mea
Media
CO W
in ^*
cO h-
m <>-
#a«
r- to
in T-
aea?
tO U3
in •»-
co m
in *-
r~~ co
in T-
to m
in *-
in m
in -^
m m
in *-
_P -P
0> 0
o o
ae*
CO O
o o"
ae#
h» O
0 0
a?#
h> O
O O
at m
tri -v
CO O
m m
c c
Debt to Asset Ratio
Mea
Media
OCM
CM »-
CM «rp
IO N-
CM ^-
JR*
•v- CO
CM v-
• V
^^
0) CM
CM T^-
gg
CM Y
CM f-
CM T-
CM i^-
r-. co
•ft
m CM
CM Y
m CM
CM ^
"^ •&
h- o
to o
aeae
r- o
10 o'
a?#
CM O
up o
at*
CM O
IO 0
p p
in
O CD
in
c b
Times Interest Earned
Mea
Media
o> to
T^
SJ5
lO^f
XX
*r- ^-
«?T
#1*
o to
«?T
O) CO
T^f
c» r-
TT
CD r-
TT
or co
T T
or co
TT
•f ^
o> or
T"?
a?*
to or
T *?
a**
"t CM
TT
#*
or CM
T-7
CO 0>
s°>
^
O)
-" CO*
tn
CO
CD
**
•< a>
. T-
w>
S" S'
Net Working Capital
Mean ($00'
Median ($00'
CM U3
V*9
U5 or
^ *?
**
CO f-.
;:<¥
t
XX
CM u>
--V
CM or
£ "?
CO 1-
TV
T- h-
^S>
O '•J-
-«?
o •*•
v"1"
aB rf
^r CM
*7 *!*
XX
CM O)
TT
a?a«
*•; *-:
"7 T
sPaP
«- f—
^7 ^7
to co
co •^:
X ae
T -^
in CM
fjt X
co m
in co
CM m
m *«•
^* *~
c c
Net WC/Total Assets:
Mee
Med IE
5-17
-------
5.2.1 Changes in Facility Costs
The starting point for estimating post-regulatory market equilibria in the market impact
model is the imposition of regulatory control costs. The market impact model requires two kinds
of compliance costs for each mill directly affected by the regulation. The first is the average
increase in variable production costs per ton of pulp that is used as an input to final product
production. The second is the estimated total annualized capital cost of the regulation. This
represents the fixed cost a facility will incur if it stays open. It is calculated on a pre-tax basis.
Table 5-10 shows the production-weighted average mill-specific pulp production variable cost
increases for each of the 17 pulp input types. The number of affected mills in the market model
producing each of the pulp types, as either inputs to final product production or for sale as
market pulp, is also shown in Table 5-10.
Mills producing pulp types 2 (bleached kraft), 3 (unbleached kraft), 14 (bleached
secondary fiber), and 15 (unbleached secondary fiber) are affected most frequently by variable
production cost increases. For each alternative, pulp type 4 (bleached sulfite) experiences the
largest production-weighted average variable cost increase, and the variable cost increase
generally rises as the stringency of the integrated regulatory alternative increases.
Table 5-11 shows the nationwide total annualized capital cost for each alternative. It is
calculated on a pre-tax basis for only the capital cost; hence the numbers are different than the
compliance costs shown in Table 4-14. The total annualized capital cost is calculated using the
mill-specific cost-of-capital estimates given in the National Census. Table 5-11 also shows the
number of facilities in the market model directly affected by capital costs, and the average,
maximum, and minimum annualized capital cost for each alternative.
53.3, Market Price and Quantity Impacts
The increases in mill-level production costs begin the market adjustment process. The
equilibrium outcome for each alternative consists of a vector of market-level product prices and
5-18
-------
w
CA
g
NH
H
VI
O
U
(X
s z?
S §1
S C^ CN
3 w*
g OC
^
<
Q
U
£
O
z
o
D
Q
O
C*
Cu
4)
1"
u
r
.
p 2
1
«
*!*•*
03 f)
5
«
*2
9 ve
C*
•**
ee
3
0.-S *
£ =H
gP
^
IB
S
*
1
*i
1
*
1
•*rf
5
*
S
'•*
s
p
3:
J£
S
P
•W
**
cn
i
S
*
00
r~
00
8
g
00
\q
00
CO
00
oo
ON
O
00
1—4
O
oo
p~
00
co
5
S
•
oo
g:
00
d
r-
00
Ov
CM
r-
oo
VO
i-H
3
ON
CM
O\
*
in
s
o>
>n
*
— ^
?.
CM
s
1
CO
1
en
CM
S
1—
TT
2
CO
CO
2
00
Y-H
Ov
«n
a
n
oo
S
0
en
d
CO
CM
d
to
CM
CM
d
CO
CM
CM
d
CO
s
o
—
s
en
rH
co
_
CO
'"'
CO
• '
9
1—4
— '
o
8
tM
S
1—4
CM
en
§
CM
CO
§
CM
to
CO
VO
o
to
^_ t
Si
en
i-i
^.
Ov
en
Ti-
en
"*
Ov
•*
VO
vn
CM
CO
CM
8
o
o
8
o
o
I
o
S
d
o
8
d
0
8
o
o
CO
JH
o
vH
r-
d
S
d
$
t-H
5?
1-4
o
d
CM
g
O
VO
^
oo
en
o
^— 1
§
Tl-
1— t
O
s
3
§
T- 4
oo
CO
d
•«*•
1-4
f-
T-4
O
00
en
m
9
CM
CM
O\
3
Ov
3
Ov
8
o\
8
d
o
vO
s?
0
d
^
CM
en
o
„.
§
•*
CM
S
"*"
8
o
o
^
5-19
-------
TABLE 5-11
NATIONWIDE TOTAL PRE-TAX ANNUA1LIZED CAPITAL COST INCREASE
(millions of $1989)
Total Annualized
Capital Cost
Number of Affected
Mills
Facility Average
Facility Maximum
Facility Median
Facility Minimum
Alt.
3
141.0
159
0.89
4.14
0.65
0.05
Alt.
16
652.7
299
2.18
19.10
0.57
*
Alt.
23
676.8
299
2.26
19.56
0.58
*
Alt.
24
695.2
299
2.36
19.78
0.59
*
Alt.
25
739.5
299
2.52
20.63
0.61
*
Alt.
26
676.8
299
2.26
19.56
0.58
*
"Less than $10,000
5-20
-------
facility-level production quantities at which total market supply and total consumer demand are
equal.
5.23.1 Product Price Impacts
Tables 5-12 through 5-17 show the equilibrium market price adjustments computed for 27
of the 37 modeled product market categories, and three composite categories that index all
market pulps, paper products and paperboard products. The tables include the baseline price
and the absolute and percentage change in price with the regulatory alternative. For each
alternative, the largest percentage change in market price is for uncoated free sheet (e.g., copy
and writing paper). For Alternatives 16, 23, 24, 25, and 26 many of the market pulp products
experience price declines due to the decrease in the demand for pulp by integrated mills.
5.22.2 Domestic Production Impacts
Tables 5-12 through 5-17 also show the equilibrium domestic production level
adjustments that result for 27 of the 37 product market categories. Nearly all of the production
level changes are minor, with the exception of bleached sulfite market pulp for Alternatives 16,
23, 24, 25, and 26 which is projected to decline by over 3 percent.
5.22.3 Import and Export Impacts
Tables 5-18 through 5-23 show the equilibrium import and export value adjustments, and
Tables 5-24 through 5-29 show the equilibrium import and export quantity adjustments that
result for 26 of the 37 modeled product categories.
Export Value. Of the five most important exports in terms of value, none of the export
declines for Alternative 3 is significant. For the other alternatives, the most significant export
decline among the most important five products is nearly 8 percent for newsprint. The most
5-21
-------
TABLE 5-12
PRICE AND QUANTITY ADJUSTMENTS (1989): SELECTED PRODUCT CATEGORIES
Regulatory Alternative 3
Product Category
Special alpha and dissolving pulp
Bleached kraft
Unbleached kraft
Bleached sulfite
Bleached secondary
Unbleached secondary
MARKET PULP TOTAL
Newsprint
Uncoatcd groundwood paper
day coated printing
Uncoated free sheet
Bleached bristols
Unbleached kraft packaging paper
Tissue
Wrapping
Shipping sack, unbl/bl sulfite
TOTAL PAPER PRODUCTS
Unbl kraft packaging paperboard
Scmichcmical paperboard
Recycled paperboard
Wet machine board
Construction paper
Insulating board
Uncrboard
Folding carton board
Milk carton board
Heavyweight cup/container
Plate, dish, and tray stock
Molded pulp products
TOTAL PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS
Base P
735.33
646.49
384.37
556.77
444.13
416.84
635.03
490.09
693.14
970.31
928.35
838.09
548.33
1,111.30
816.70
656.33
843.14
395.55
361.50
381.52
629.15
392.85
338.32
543.04
721.33
719.37
. 700.25
686.05
1,196.29
432.66
AP
0.23
-0.04
-0.13
0.22
0.25
0.16
0.01
0.10
0.02
2.18
6.65
0.52
0.05
0.40
0.10
0.20
2.62
030
0.15
0.17
0.55
0.05
0.00
0.09
0.72
0.21
0.43
039
0.03
0.27
%AP
*
*
*
*
*
#
*
*
*
41
41
4>
*
*
*
*
»
*
*
*
41
*
4>
*
*
*
41
4>
*
4t
TOTAL ALL PRODUCTS
BaseQ
1,470
9,207
320
359
120
117
11493
5,678
2,090
9,157
11341
779
2,943
5392
157
93
40,247
19375
5,927
8,796
80
667
92
376
2395
1,205
453
219
227
40,607
92,447
AQ
0
-25
-1
0
0
0
-27
-1
0
-63
20
-1
-1
-1
0
0
-31
-16
-2
2
0
0
0
-1
-5
-2
-1
0
0
-27
-85
%AQ
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
4>
*
4t
*
4>
*
*
4>
4>
*
4>
*
*
*
*
4>
*
4>
4i
4i
*
*
*
*
P=price (SAon) Q=domestic production (000 ton/yr) A="change in"
Totals and percent changes might not be exact because of rounding.
*=less than 1%
5-22
-------
TABLE 5-13
PRICE AND QUANTITY ADJUSTMENTS (1989): SELECTED PRODUCT CATEGORIES
Regulatory Alternative 16
Product Category
Special alpha and dissolving pulp
Bleached kraft
Unbleached kraft
Bleached sulfite
Bleached secondary
Unbleached secondary
MARKET PULP TOTAL
Newsprint
Uncoated groundwood paper
Clay coated printing
Uncoated free sheet
Bleached bristols
Unbl kraft packaging paper
Tissue
Wrapping
Shipping sack, unbl/bl sulfite
TOTAL PAPER PRODUCTS
Unbl kraft packaging paperboard
Semichemical paperboard
Recycled paperboard
Wet machine board
Construction paper
Insulating board
Linerboard
Folding carton board
Milk carton board
Heavyweight cup/container
Plate, dish, and tray stock
Molded pulp products
TOTAL PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS
BaseP
735.33
646.49
384.37
556.77
444.13
416.84
635.03
490.09
693.14
970.31
928.35
838.09
548.33
1,11130
816.70
656.33
843.14
395.55
361.50
381.52
629.15
39i85
338.32
543.04
721.33
719.37
700.25
686.05
1,196.29
43X66
AP
0.62
-1.00
-0.06
0.88
0.21
-7.84
-0.72
0.90
0.11
2.03
25.57
0.83
0.23
6.85
13.91
033
7.89
0.25
1.00
3.61
9.58
0.04
0.22
0.10
0.23
-0.11
-0.06
-0.12
0.04
1.07
%AP
*
*
«
*
*
-1.9
*
*
*
*
*
*
4
*
1.7
»
*
*
*
*
L5
*
*
a
*
*
*
*
*
•
TOTAL ALL PRODUCTS
Base Q
1,470
9,207
320
359
120
117
11493
5,678
2,090
9,157
11341
779
2,943
5392
157
93
40,247
19375
5,927
8,796
80
667
92
376
2395
1,205
453
219
227
40,607
92,447
AQ
-2
-22
-1
-11
0
-2
-39
-52
0
-54
-92
-2
-1
-13
2
-1
-218
-13
0
-31
0
0
0
-2
-1
1
0
0
0
-45
-302
%AQ
*
*
*
-3.2
-
-1.4
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
1.2
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
- +
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
P=price ($Aon) Q=domestic production (000 ton/yr) A="change in"
Totals and percent changes might not be exact because of rounding.
"=less than 1%
5-23
-------
TABLE 5-14
PRICE AND QUANTITY ADJUSTMENTS (1989): SELECTED PRODUCT CATEGORIES
Regulatory Alternative 23
Product Category
Special alpha and dissolving pulp
Bleached kraft
Unbleached kraft
Bleached sulfite
Bleached secondary
Unbleached secondary
MARKET PULP TOTAL
Newsprint
Uncoated groundwood paper
day coated printing
Uncoated free sheet
Bleached bristols
Unbl kraft packaging paper
Tissue
Wrapping
Shipping sack, unbl/bl sulfite
TOTAL PAPER PRODUCTS
Unbl kraft packaging paperboard
Seraichemical paperboard
Recycled paperboard
Wet machine board
Construction paper
Insulating board
Lincrboard
Folding carton board
Milk carton board
Heavyweight cup/container
Plate, dish, and tray stock
Molded pulp products •
TOTAL PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS
BaseP
735.33
646.49
384.37
556.77
444.13
416.84
635.03
490.09
693.14
970.31
928.35
838.09
548.33
1,11130
816.70
656.33
843.14
395.55
361.50
381.52
629.15
39X85
338.32
543.04
721.33
719.37
700.25
686.05
1.196.29
432.66
AP
0.62
-1.00
-0.06
0.88
0.21
-7.84
-0.72
0.90
0.11
2.14
25.57
1.51
0.23
6.85
14.00
0.47
7.93
0.27
0.99
3.62
9.58
0.04
0.22
0.21
0.67
0.06
030
0.15
0.04
1.13
%AP
*
*
*
*
•
-1.9
*
*
*
*
2.8
*
*
*
1.7
*
*
*
*
*
1.5
*
*
*
+
*
*
*
*
*
TOTAL ALL PRODUCTS
BaseQ
1,470
9,207
320
359
120
117
1L593
5,678
2,090
9,157
11341
779
2,943
5392
157
93
40,247
19375
5,927
8,796
80
667
92
376
2395
1,205
453
219
227
40,607
92,447
AQ
-2
-29
-1
-11
0
-2
-45
-53
0
-60
-96
-4
-1
-14
2
-1
-234
-14
0
-31
0
0
0
-3
-6
-1
-1
0
0
-58
-337
%AQ
*
*
*
-3.2
*
-1.4
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
1.2
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
P=price ($Aon) Q=domestic production (000 ton/yr) A="change
Totals and percent changes might not be exact because of rounding.
*=less than 1%
5-24
-------
TABLE 5-15
PRICE AND QUANTITY ADJUSTMENTS (1989): SELECTED PRODUCT CATEGORIES
Regulatory Alternative 24
Product Category
Special alpha and dissolving pulp
Bleached kraft
Unbleached kraft
Bleached sulfite
Bleached secondary
Unbleached secondary
MARKET PULP TOTAL
Newsprint
Uncoated groundwood paper
Clay coated printing
Uncoated free sheet
Bleached bristols
Unbl kraft packaging paper
Tissue
Wrapping
Shipping sack, unbl/bl sulfite
TOTAL PAPER PRODUCTS
Unbl kraft packaging paperboard
Semichemical paperboard
Recycled paperboard
Wet machine board
Construction paper
Insulating board
Linerboard
Folding carton board
Milk carton board
Heavyweight cup/container
Plate, dish, and tray stock
Molded pulp products
TOTAL PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS
Base P
735.33
646.49
384.37
556.77
444.13
416.84
635.03
490.09
693.14
970.31
928.35
838.09
548.33
1,11130
816.70
656.33
843.14
395.55
361.50
381.52
629.15
392.85
338.32
543.04
721.33
719.37
700.25
686.05
1,196.29
43X66
AP
0.62
-1.01
-0.06
0.88
0.21
-7.84
-0.73
0.90
0.11
2.14
25.57
1.53
0.20
6.65
14.00
0.47
7.95
0.27
0.90
3.63
9.58
0.04
0.22
0.21
0.87
0.18
0.45
030
0.04
1.14
%AP
*
*
*
*
*
-1.9
*
41
*
*
2.8.
*
*
*
*
*
*
4>
*
*
1.5
*
«
#
«
*
0
0
*
*
TOTAL ALL PRODUCTS
Base Q
1,470
9,207
320
359
120
117
11493
5,678
2,090
9,157
11341
779
2,943
5392
157
93
40,247
19375
5,927
8,796
80
667
92
376
2395
1,205
453
219
227
40,607
92,447
AQ
-2
-29
-1
-11
0
-2
-46
-53
0
-60
-96
-4
-1
-15
2
-1
-234
-15
-1
-31
0
0
0
-3
-6
-1
-1
0
0
-59
-340
%AQ
*
*
*
-3.2
*
-1.4
*
*
+
*
*
*
*
*
1.2
*
*
*
*
*
*
4>
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
P=price (SAon) Q=domestic production (000 ton/yr) A="change
Totals and percent changes might not be exact because of rounding.
in"
'sless than 1%
5-25
-------
TABLE S-16
PRICE AND QUANTITY ADJUSTMENTS (1989): SELECTED PRODUCT CATEGORIES
Regulatory Alternative 25
Product Category
Special alpha and dissolving pulp
Bleached kraft
Unbleached kraft
Bleached sulfite
Bleached secondary
Unbleached secondary
MARKET PULP TOTAL
Newsprint
Uncoated groundwood paper
day coated printing
Uncoated free sheet
Bleached bristols
Unbl kraft packaging paper
Tissue
Wrapping
Shipping sack, unbl/bl sulfite
TOTAL PAPER PRODUCTS
Unbl kraft packaging paperboard
Scmichemical paperboard
Recycled paperboard
Wet machine board
Construction paper
Insulating board
Linerboard
Folding carton board
Milk carton board
Heavyweight cup/container
Plate, dish, and tray stock
Molded pulp products
TOTAL PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS
BaseP
735.33
646.49
384.37
556.77
444.13
416.84
635.03
490.09
693.14
970.31
928.35
838.09
548.33
1,1 11 JO
816.70
656.33
843.14
395.55
361.50
381.52
629.15
392.85
338.32
543.04
721.33
719.37
700.25
686.05
1.196.29
432.66
AP
0.62
-1.01
-0.06
0.88
0.21
-7.84
-0.73
0.89
0.11
2.19
25.57
1.61
0.20
6.61
14.00
0.52
7.95
0.27
0.88
3.61
9.58
0.04
0.22
0.24
0.97
0.18
0.50
0.30
0.04
1.14
%AP
*
*
*
*
*
-1.9
*
*
*
*
2.8
*
*
*
1.7
*
1.0
*
*
*
1.5
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
TOTAL ALL PRODUCTS
Base Q
1,470
9,207
320
359
120
117
11493
5,678
2,090
9,157
11341
779
2,943
5392
157
93
40,247
19375
5,927
8,796
80
667
92
376
2395
1,205
453
219
227
40,607
92,447
AQ
-2
-30
-1
-11
0
-2
-46
-54
0
-60
-97
-4
-1
-15
2
-1
-235
-15
-1
-31
0
0
0
-4
-6
-1
-1
0
0
-61
-350
%AQ
*
*
*
-3.2
*
-1.4
*
*
+
*
*
*
*
*
1.1
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
4>
*
*
*
*
*
*
P=price (SAon) Q=doraestic production (000 ton/yr) A="change in"
Totals and percent changes might not be exact because of rounding.
"=1685 than 1%
5-26
-------
TABLE 5-17
PRICE AND QUANTITY ADJUSTMENTS (1989): SELECTED PRODUCT CATEGORIES
Regulatory Alternative 26
Product Category
Special alpha and dissolving pulp
Bleached kraft
Unbleached kraft
Bleached sulfite
Bleached secondary
Unbleached secondary
MARKET PULP TOTAL
Newsprint
Uncoated groundwood paper
Clay coated printing
Uncoated free sheet
Bleached bristols
Unbl kraft packaging paper
Tissue
Wrapping
Shipping sack, unbl/bl sulfite
TOTAL PAPER PRODUCTS
Unbl kraft packaging paperboard
Semichernical paperboard
Recycled paperboard
Wet machine board
Construction paper
Insulating board
Linerboard
Folding carton board
Milk carton board
Heavyweight cup/container
Plate, dish, and tray stock
Molded pulp products
TOTAL PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS
Base P
735.33
646.49
384.37
556.77
444.13
416.84
635.03
490.09
693.14
970.31
928.35
838.09
548.33
1,11130
816.70
656.33
843.14
395.55
361.50
381.52
629.15
39X85
338.32
543.04
721.33
719.37
700.25
686.05
1.196.29
432.66
AP
0.23
-1.49
-0.12
0.84
0.18
-7.91
-1.15
0.76
0.11
2.09
25.15
1.58
0.07
5.85
13.75
0.47
7.67
0.28
0.40
3.62
9.85
0.05
0.18
0.21
0.97
0.13
0.50
030
0.01
1.07
%AP
*
*
*
*
*
-1.9
*
*
*
*
2.1
*
*
*
1.7
*
*
*
*
*
1.6
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
TOTAL ALL PRODUCTS
Base Q
1,470
9,207
320
359
120
117
11^93
5,678
2,090
9,157
11341
779
2,943
5392
157
93
40,247
19375
5,927
8,796
80
667
92
376
2395
1,205
453
219
227
40,607
92,447
AQ
0
-30
-1
-11
0
-2
-44
-54
0
-58
-97
-4
-1
-18
2
-1
-235
-14
-3
-31
0
0
0
-3
-6
-1
-1
0
0
-59
-220
%AQ
+
*
*
-3.1
*
-1.5
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
1.2
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
#
P=price (SAon) Q=domestic production (000 ton/yr) A="change in" *=less than 1%
Totals and percent changes might not be exact because of rounding.
5-27
-------
TABLE 5-18
FOREIGN TRADE VALUE ADJUSTMENTS (1989):
SELECTED PRODUCT CATEGORIES
Regulatory Alternative 3
(millions of $1989)
Product Category
Special alpha and dissolving pulp
Bleached kraft
Unbleached kraft
Bleached sulfite
Bleached secondary
Unbleached secondary
MARKET PULP TOTAL
Newsprint
Uncoated groundwood paper
day coated printing
Uncoated free sheet
Bleached bristols
Cotton fiber writing
Unbl kraft packaging paper
Tissue
Wrapping
Shipping sack, unbl/bl sulfite
TOTAL PAPER PRODUCTS
Unb! kraft packaging paperboard
Semichcmical paperboard
Recycled paperboard
Construction paper
Hnerboard
Folding carton board
Milk carton board
Heavyweight cup/container
Plate, dish, and tray stock
Molded pulp products
TOTAL PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS
TOTAL ALL PRODUCTS
BaseSX
614.8
3,024.0
69.8
181.1
0
173
3,906.9
306.2
61.0
163.5
11Z9
39.2
84.1
16.7
23.0
13
27.2
1,148.2
974.3
113
70.6
13.1
153.7
139.8
380.7
7.2
7.1
15.2
1,809.4
6,864.5
A$X
-0.6
-0.9
-0.4
-1.9
0
-0.1
-1.2
-2.7
0
-6.4
-6.7
-0.6
-0.3
0
0
0
-0.2
-16.1
-4.1
0
-0.3
0
-0.7
-1.2
-0.8
0
0
0
-7.4
-24.7
%A$X
*
*
*
-1.0
*
*
*
*
4>
-3.9
-5.9
-1.4
*
*
#
*
*
-1.4
*
. *
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
Base$I
208.9
2,426.4
33.4
199.5
274.5
0
3,142.6
4,191.9
903.9
751.0
0
495
1,215.4
131.2
134.2
1.9
1.6
7,6393
653
42.7
63.0
743
6.6
8.8
8.7
8.5
83
233
326.2
11,108.2
A$I
0.1
-0.3
-0.3
0.6
1.7
0
1.8
1.2
0.1
12.9
0
0.1
1.4
0
0.1
0
0
22.9
0.1
0
0.1
0
0
0.4
0.1
0.2
0.2
0
1.8
265
%A$I
*
*
-1.0
*
*
*
*
*
*
1.7
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
4.6
1.1
2.7
2.5
*
*
*
SX^export value $I=import value
Totals and percent changes might not be exact
A="change in"
because of rounding.
•=less than 1%
5-28
-------
TABLE 5-19
FOREIGN TRADE VALUE ADJUSTMENTS (1989):
SELECTED PRODUCT CATEGORIES
Regulatory Alternative 16
(millions of $1989)
Product Category
Special alpha and dissolving pulp
Bleached kraft
Unbleached kraft
Bleached sulfite
Bleached secondary
Unbleached secondary
MARKET PULP TOTAL
Newsprint
Uncoated groundwood paper
Clay coated printing
Uncoated free sheet
Bleached bristols
Cotton fiber writing
Unbl kraft packaging paper
Tissue
Wrapping
Shipping sack, unbl/bl sulfite
TOTAL PAPER PRODUCTS
Unbl kraft packaging paperboard
Semicbemical paperboard
Recycled paperboard
Construction paper
Linerboard
Folding carton board
Milk carton board
Heavyweight cup/container
Plate, dish, and tray stock
Molded pulp products
TOTAL PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS
TOTAL ALL PRODUCTS
BaseSX
614.8
3,024.0
69.8
181.1
0
173
3,906.9
306.2
61.0
163.5
112.9
39.2
84.1
16.7
23.0
73
27.2
1,148.2
974.3
11.3
70.6
13.1
153.7
139.8
380.7
7.2
7.1
15.2
1,809.4
6,864.5
A$X
-1.8
223
0.2
-7.2
0
3.2
16.8
-23.5
-0.2
-6.0
-23.4
-0.9
-1.9
-0.1
0.1
-4.2
-0.3
-59.5
-3.5
-0.2
-5.4
0
-0.8
-0.4
0.4
0
0
0
-9.7
-25.9
%A$X
*
*
*
-4.0
*
18.6
*
-7.7
*
-3.7
-20.8
-2.3
-2.3
*
*
-57.1
-1.2
-5.2
*
-1.6
-7.6
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
BaseSI
208.9
2,426.4
33.4
199.5
274.5
0
3,142.6
4,191.9
903.9
751.0
0
49.5
1,215.4
131.2
134.2
1.9
1.6
7,6393
653
42.7
63.0
743
6.6
8.8
8.7
8.5
83
233
326.2
11,108.2
A$I
03
-7.5
-0.2
2.2
1.4
0
-3.7
113
0.4
12.0
0
0.2
9.4
0.2
1.2
0.5
0
43.2
0.1
03
1.5
0
0
0
0
0
-0.1
0.1
1.8
41.3
%A$I
*
*
*
1.1
*
*
*
*
*
1.6
*
*
*
*
*
28.0
*
*
*
*
2.5
*
*
.1.5
*
*
*
*
*
*
$X=export value $I=import value
Totals and percent changes might not be exact
A="change in"
because of rounding.
*=less than 1%
5-29
-------
TABLE 5-20
FOREIGN TRADE VALUE ADJUSTMENTS (1989):
SELECTED PRODUCT CATEGORIES
Regulatory Alternative 23
(millions of $1989)
Product Category
Special alpha and dissolving pulp
Bleached kraft
Unbleached kraft
Bleached sulfite
Bleached secondary
Unbleached secondary
MARKET PULP TOTAL
Newsprint
Uncoated groundwood paper
Clay coated printing
Uncoated free sheet
Bleached bristols
Cotton fiber writing
Unbl kraft packaging paper
Tissue
Wrapping
Shipping sack, unbl/bl sulfite
TOTAL PAPER PRODUCTS
Unbl kraft packaging paperboard
Scmichcmical paperboard
Recycled paperboard
Construction paper
Lincrboard
Folding canon board
Milk carton board
Heavyweight cup/container
Plate, dish, and tray stock
Molded pulp products
TOTAL PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS
TOTAL ALL PRODUCTS
Base$X
614.8
3,024.0
69.8
181.1
0
173
3,906.9
306.2
61.0
163.5
11Z9
39.2
84.1
16.7
23.0
73
27.2
1,148.2
974.3
11.3
70.6
13.1
153.7
139.8
380.7
7.2
7.1
15.2
1,809.4
6.864.5
A$X
-1.8
22.2
0.2
-7.2
0
3.2
16.7
-23.5
-0.2
-6.3
-23.4
-1.6
-1.9
-0.1
0.1
-4.2
-0.4
-60.8
-3.7
-0.2
-5.4
0
-1.7
-1.1
-0.2
0
0
0
-12.5
-56.6
%A$X
*
*
*
-4.0
*
18.6
#
*
-7.7
*
-3.9
-20.8
-4.2
-2.3
*
*
-57.3
-1.6
-5.3
*
-1.6
-7.6
*
-1.1
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
Base $1
208.9
2,426.4
33.4
199.5
274.5
0
3,142.6
4,191.9
903.9
751.0
0
49.5
1,215.4
131.2
134.2
1.9
1.6
7,639.3
65.3
42.7
63.0
743
6.6
8.8
8.7
8.5
83
233
326.2
11,108.2
A$I
03
-7.5
-0.2
2.2
1.4
0
-3.7
113
0.4
12.6
0
0.4
9.4
0.2
1.2
0.5
0
44.0
0.1
0.3
1.5
0
0.1
0.4
0
0.2
0.1
0.1
2.9
43.2
%A$I
*
*
*
1.1
*
*
*
*
*
1.7
*
*
*
*
*
28.2
1.1
*
*
*
2.5
*
13
4.3
*
1.9
1.0
*
*
*
SX=export value SI=import value
Totals and percent changes might not be exact
A="change
because of rounding.
in"
*=less than 1%
5-30
-------
TABLE 5-21
FOREIGN TRADE VALUE ADJUSTMENTS (1989):
SELECTED PRODUCT CATEGORIES
Regulatory Alternative 24
(millions of $1989)
Product Category
Special alpha and dissolving pulp
Bleached kraft
Unbleached kraft
Bleached sulfite
Bleached secondary
Unbleached secondary
MARKET PULP TOTAL
Newsprint
Uncoated groundwood paper
Clay coated printing
Uncoated free sheet
Bleached bristols
Cotton fiber writing
Unbl kraft packaging paper
Tissue
Wrapping
Shipping sack, unbl/bl sulfite
TOTAL PAPER PRODUCTS
Unbl kraft packaging paperboard
Semichemical paperboard
Recycled paperboard
Construction paper
Linerboard
Folding carton board
Milk carton board
Heavyweight cup/container
Plate, dish, and tray stock
Molded pulp products
TOTAL PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS
TOTAL ALL PRODUCTS
BaseSX
614.8
3,024.0
69.8
181.1
0
173
3,906.9
306.2
61.0
163.5
11X9
39.2
84.1
16.7
23.0
73
27.2
1.148.2
974.3
113
70.6
13.1
153.7
139.8
380.7
7.2
7.1
15.2
1309.4
6364.5
A$X
-1.8
22.6
0.2
-7.2
0
32
17.0
-23.5
-0.2
-6.3
-23.4
-1.7
-1.9
-0.1
0.1
-4.2
-0.4
-60.8
-3.7
-0.2
-5.4
0
-1.7
-1.5
-0.7
0
0
0
-13.3
-57.1
%A$X
*
*
*
-4.0
#
18.6
*
-7.7
*
-3.9
-20.8
-4.2
-2.3
*
*
-57.3
-1.6
-5.3
*
-1.4
-7.6
*
-1.1
-1.1
*
*
*
*
*
*
Base$I
208.9
2,426.4
33.4
199.5
274.5
0
3,14Z6
4,191.9
903.9
751.0
0
49.5
1,215.4
131.2
134.2
1.9
1.6
7,6393
653
42.7
63.0
743
6.6
8.8
8.7
8.5
83
233
326.2
11,108.2
A$I
03
-7.6
-0.2
2.2
1.4
0
-3.8
113
0.4
12.6
0
0.4
9.4
0.2
1.2
0.5
0
44.4
0.1
0.2
1.6
0
0.1
0.5
0.1
0.2
0.2
0.1
33
43.9
%A$I
*
*
*
1.1
*
*
*
*
1.7
1.7
*
*
*
*
*
28.2
1.1
*
*
*
2.5
*
1.3
5.6
*
2.8
1.9
*
1.0
*
$X=export value $I=import
Totals and percent changes might not be exact
value
because of rounding.
A="change in"
•=less than 1%
5-31
-------
TABLE 5-22
FOREIGN TRADE VALUE ADJUSTMENTS (1989):
SELECTED PRODUCT CATEGORIES
Regulatory Alternative 25
(millions of $1989)
Product Category
Special alpha and dissolving pulp
Bleached kraft
Unbleached kraft
Bleached sulfite
Bleached secondary
Unbleached secondary
MARKET PULP TOTAL
Newsprint
Uncoatcd groundwood paper
day coated printing
Uncoatcd free sheet
Bleached bristols
Cotton fiber writing
Unbl kraft packaging paper
Tissue
Wrapping
Shipping sack, unbl/bl sulfite
TOTAL PAPER PRODUCTS
Unbl kraft packaging paperboard
Scmichemica] paperboard
Recycled paperboard
Construction paper
Linerboard
Folding carton board
Milk carton board
Heavyweight cup/container
Plate, dish, and tray stock
Molded pulp products
TOTAL PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS
TOTAL ALL PRODUCTS
Base$X
614.8
3,024.0
69.8
181.1
0
173
3,906.9
306.2
61.0
163.5
112.9
39.2
84.1
16.7
23.0
7.3
27.2
1,148.2
974.3
113
70.6
13.1
153.7
139.8
380.7
7.2
7.1
15.2
1,809.4
6364.5
A$X
-1.8
22.6
0.2
-7.2
0
3.2
17.0
-23.3
-0.2
-6.5
-23.4
-1.7
-1.9
-0.1
0.1
-4.2
-0.5
-60.8
-3.7
-0.2
-5.4
0
-1.9
-1.6
-0.7
0
0
0
-13.7
-57.5
%A$X
*
*
*
-4.0
*
18.6
*
-7.6
*
-3.9
-20.8
-4.4
-2.3
*
*
-57.3
-1.8
-5.3
*
-1.4
-7.6
*
-1.3
-1.2
*
*
*
*
*
*
Base $1
208.9
2,426.4
33.4
199.5
274.5
0
3,142.6
4,191.9
903.9
751.0
0
49.5
1,215.4
131.2
134.2
1.9
1.6
7,6393
653
42.7
63.0
743
6.6
8.8
8.7
8.5
8.3
233
326.2
11,108.2
A$I
03
-7.6
-0.2
2.2
1.4
0
-3.8
11.2
0.4
12.9
0
0.4
9.4
0.2
1.2
0.5
0
44.6
0.1
0.2
1.5
0
0.1
0.5
0.1
03
0.2
0.1
3.5
443
%A$I
*
*
*
1.1
*
*
*
*
*
1.7
*
*
*
*
*
28.2
1.2
*
*
*
2.5
*
1.4
6.3
*
3.1
1.9
*
1.1
*
SX=export value $I=irnport
Totals and percent changes might not'-be exact
value
because of rounding.
A="change in"
*=less than
5-32
-------
TABLE 5-23
FOREIGN TRADE VALUE ADJUSTMENTS (1989):
SELECTED PRODUCT CATEGORIES
Regulatory Alternative 26
(millions of $1989)
Product Category
Special alpha and dissolving pulp
Bleached kraft
Unbleached kraft
Bleached sulfite
Bleached secondary
Unbleached secondary
MARKET PULP TOTAL
Newsprint
Uncoated groundwood paper
Clay coated printing
Uncoated free sheet
Bleached bristols
Cotton fiber writing
Unbl kraft packaging paper
Tissue
Wrapping
Shipping sack, unbl/bl sulfite
TOTAL PAPER PRODUCTS
Unbl kraft packaging paperboard
Semichemical paperboard
Recycled paperboard
Construction paper
Linerboard
Folding carton board
Milk carton board
Heavyweight cup/container
Plate, dish, and tray stock
Molded pulp products
TOTAL PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS
TOTAL ALL PRODUCTS
Base$X
614.8
3,024.0
69.8
181.1
0
173
3,906.9
306.2
61.0
163.5
112.9
39.2
84.1
16.7
23.0
73
27.2
1,148.2
974.3
113
70.6
13.1
153.7
139.8
380.7
7.2
7.1
15.2
1,809.4
6,864.5
A$X
-0.6
333
0.4
-6.9
0
33
295
-20.0
-0.2
-6.2
-23.1
-1.7
-1.8
0
0.1
-4.1
-0.4
-56.6
-3.9
-0.1
-5.4
0
-1.7
-1.6
-0.5
0
0
0
-13.4
-40.5
%A$X
*
1.1
«
-3.8
0
18.8
*
-6.5
4
-3.8
-20.5
-4.4
-2.1
*
*
-56.7
-1.6
-4.9
*
*
-7.6
*
-1.1
-1.2
*
*
*
*
*
*
BaseSI
208.9
2,426.4
33.4
199.5
274.5
0
3,142.6
4,191.9
903.9
751.0
0
495
1,215.4
131.2
134.2
1.9
1.6
7,6393
653
42.7
63.0
743
6.6
8.8
8.7
85
8.3
233
326.2
11,108.2
A$I
0.1
-11.2
-0.3
2.1
1.2
0
-8.1
95
0.4
123
0
0.4
8.9
0.1
1.0
05
0
41.1
0.1
0.1
1.5
0
0.1
0.5
0.1
03
0.2
0
33
363
%A$I
*
*
*
1.1
*
*
*
*
*
1.6
*
*
*
*
*
27.6
1.1
*
*
*
2.5
*
1.3
63
*
3.1
1.9
*
1.0
*
$X=export value $1=import
Totals and percent changes might not be exact
value
because of rounding.
A="change
'=less than 1%
5-33
-------
TABLE 5-24
FOREIGN TRADE QUANTITY ADJUSTMENTS (1989):
SELECTED PRODUCT CATEGORIES
Regulatory Alternative 3
(000 tonii/yr)
Product Category
Special alpha and dissolving pulp
Bleached kraft
Unbleached kraft
Bleached sulfite
Bleached secondary
Unbleached secondary
MARKET PULP TOTAL
Newsprint
Uncoated groundwood paper
Clay coated printing
Uncoated free sheet
Bleached bristols
Cotton fiber writing paper
Unbl kraft packaging paper
Tissue
Wrapping
Shipping sack, unbl/bl sulfite
TOTAL PAPER PRODUCTS
Unbl kraft packaging paperboard
Sernichernical paperboard
Recycled paperboard
Construction paper
Lincrboard
Folding carton board
Milk carton board
Heavyweight cup/container
Plate, dish, and tray stock
Molded pulp products
TOTAL PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS
TOTAL ALL PRODUCTS
BaseX
836
4,678
181
325
0
41
6,062
625
88
169
122
47
41
30
21
9
42
1391
2,463
31
185
33
283
194
529
10
10
13
3,807
11,260
AX
-1
2
1
-3
0
0
-2
-6
0
-7
-8
-1
0
0
0
o •
0
-24
-12
0
-1
0
-1
-2
-1
0
0
0
-18
-44
%AX
*
*
*
-1.1
*
*
*
*
*
-4.1
-6.6
-1.5
*
*
*
*
*
-1.7
*
*
*
*
*
-1.0
*
*
*
*
*
*
Basel
284
3,753
87
358
618
0
5,100
8,553
1304
774
0
59
596
239
121
2
2
11,811
165
118
165
189
12
12
12
12
12
19
743
17,654
AI
0
0
-1
1
4
0
3
1
0
11
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
15
0
0
0
0
0
1
0
0
0
0
3
21
%AI
*
*
-1.0
*
*
*
*
*
*
1.5
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
4!
*
*
*
*
*
4.5
1.1
*
2.4
*
+
*
X » export quantity I = import quantity
Totals and percent changes might not be exact
A = "change in"
because of rounding.
= less than 1%
5-34
-------
TABLE 5-25
FOREIGN TRADE QUANTITY ADJUSTMENTS (1989):
SELECTED PRODUCT CATEGORIES
Regulatory Alternative 16
(000 tons/yr)
Product Category
Special alpha and dissolving pulp
Bleached kraft
Unbleached kraft
Bleached sulfite
Bleached secondary
Unbleached secondary
MARKET PULP TOTAL
Newsprint
Uncoated groundwood paper
Clay coated printing
Uncoated free sheet
Bleached bristols
Cotton fiber writing paper
Unbl kraft packaging paper
Tissue
Wrapping
Shipping sack, unbl/bl sulfite
TOTAL PAPER PRODUCTS
Unbl kraft packaging paperboard
Semichemical paperboard
Recycled paperboard
Construction paper
Unerboard
Folding carton board
Milk carton board
Heavyweight cup/container
Plate, dish, and tray stock
Molded pulp products
TOTAL PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS
TOTAL ALL PRODUCTS
BaseX
836
4,678
181
325
0
41
6,062
625
88
169
122
47
41
30
21
9
42
1391
2,463
31
185
33
283
194
529
10
10
13
3,807
11,260
AX
-3
42
1
-13
0
9
35
-49
0
-7
-28
-1
-1
0
0
-5
-1
-94
-10
-1
-16
0
-2
-1
1
0
0
0
-28
-87
%AX
*
*
*
-4.1
*
20.9
*
-7.8
*
-3.9
-22.9
-2.4
-2,6
*
*
-57.8
-1.2
-6.7
*
-1.9
-8.5
*
*
*
*
«
*
*
*
*
Basel
284
3,753
87
358
618
0
5,100
8^53
1^04
774
0
59
596
239
121
2
2
11,811
165
118
165
189
12
12
12
12
12
19
743
17,654
AI
0
-6
0
3
3
0
0
7
0
11
0
0
2
0
0
1
0
25
.0
0
2
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
3
28
%AI
*
*
*
1.0
*
*
*
*
*
1.4
*
*
*
*
*
25.8
*
*
41
*
1.5
*
*
1.4
4>
*
*
*
*
*
X = export quantity I = import quantity
Totals and percent changes might not be exact
A = "change in"
because of rounding.
= less than 1%
5-35
-------
TABLE 5-26
FOREIGN TRADE QUANTITY ADJUSTMENTS (1989):
SELECTED PRODUCT CATEGORIES
Regulatory Alternative 23
(000 tons/yr)
Product Category
Special alpha and dissolving pulp
Bleached kraft
Unbleached kraft
Bleached sulfite
Bleached secondary
Unbleached secondary
MARKET PULP TOTAL
Newsprint
Uncoatcd groundwood paper
Clay coated printing
Uncoatcd free sheet
Bleached bristols
Cotton fiber writing paper
Unbl kraft packaging paper
Tissue
Wrapping
Shipping sack, unbl/bl sulfite
TOTAL PAPER PRODUCTS
Unbl kraft packaging paperboard
Scraichcmical paperboard
Recycled paperboard
Construction paper
Lincrboard
Folding carton board
Milk carton board
Heavyweight cup/container
Plate, dish, and tray stock
Molded pulp products
TOTAL PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS
TOTAL ALL PRODUCTS
BaseX
836
4,678
181
325
0
41
6,062
625
88
169
122
47
41
30
21
9
42
1391
2,463
31
185
33
283
194
529
10
10
13
3,807
11 .260
AX
-3
42
1
-13
, 0
9
34
-49
0
-7
-28
-2
-1
0
0
-5
-1
-95
-11
-1
-16
0
-3
-2
0
0
0
0
-33
-94
%AX
*
*
*
-4.1
*
20.9
*
-7.8
*
-4.1
-22.9
*
*
*
*
-58.1
-1.7
-6.8
*
-1.8
-8.5
*
-1.1
*
*
*
*
*
*
* .
Basel
284
3,753
87
3581
618
0
5,100
8453
1304
774
0
59
596
239
121
2
2
11,811
165
118
165
189
12
12
12
12
12
19
743
17,654
AI
0
-6
0
3
3
0
0
7
0
11
0
0
2
0
0
1
0
26
0
0
2
0
0
1
0
0
0
0
4
30
%AI
*
*
*
1.0
*
*
*
*
*
1.5
*
*
*
*
*
26.0
1.0
* ,
*
*
1.5
*
1.2
4.2
*
1.8
*
*
*
*
X = export quantity I = import quantity
Totals and percent changes may not be exact due
A = "change in"
to rounding.
= less than 1%
5-36
-------
TABLE 5-27
FOREIGN TRADE QUANTITY ADJUSTMENTS (1989):
SELECTED PRODUCT CATEGORIES
Regulatory Alternative 24
(000 tons/yr)
Product Category
Special alpha and dissolving pulp
Bleached kraft
Unbleached kraft
Bleached sulfite
Bleached secondary
Unbleached secondary
MARKET PULP TOTAL
Newsprint
Uncoated groundwood paper
Clay coated printing
Uncoated free sheet
Bleached bristols
Cotton fiber writing paper
Unbl kraft packaging paper
Tissue
Wrapping
Shipping sack, unbl/bl sulfite
TOTAL PAPER PRODUCTS
Unbl kraft packaging paperboard
Semichemical paperboard
Recycled paperboard
Construction paper
Linerboard
Folding carton board
Milk carton board
Heavyweight cup/container
Plate, dish, and tray stock
Molded pulp products
TOTAL PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS
TOTAL ALL PRODUCTS
Base X
836
4,678
181
325
0
41
6,062
625
88
169
122
47
41
30
21
9
42
1391
2,463
31
185
33
283
194
529
10
10
13
3307
11,260
AX
-3
42
1
-13
0
9
35
-49
0
-7
-28
-2
-1
0
0
-5
-1
-95
-11
-1
-16
0
-3
-2
-1
0
0
0
-34
-94
%AX
*
*
*
-4.1
*
20.9
*
-7.8
#
-4.1
-22.9
-4.4
-2.6
*
*
-58.1
-1.7
-6.9
*
-1.7
-8.5
«
-1.1
-1.2
*
e
*
«
*
*
Base I
284
3,753
87
358
618
0
5,100
8453
1304
774
0
59
596
239
121
2
2
11,811
165
118
165
189
12
12
12
12
12
19
743
17,654
AI
0
-6
0
3
3
0
0
7
0
11
0
0
2
0
0
1
0
26
0
0
2
0
0
1
0
0
0
0
5
31
%AI
*
*
*
1.0
*
*
*
*
*
1.5
*
*
*
*
*
26.0
1.0
*
*
*
1.5
*
1.2
5.5
*
*
*
*
*
*
X = export quantity I = import quantity
Totals and percent changes may not be exact due
A = "change in"
to rounding.
= less than 1%
5-37
-------
TABLE 5-28
FOREIGN TRADE QUANTITY ADJUSTMENTS (1989);
SELECTED PRODUCT CATEGORIES
Regulatory Alternative 25
(000 tons/yr)
Product Category
Special alpha and dissolving pulp
Bleached kraft
Unbleached kraft
Bleached sulfite
Bleached secondary
Unbleached secondary
MARKET PULP TOTAL
Newsprint
Uncoated groundwood paper
day coated printing
Uncoated free sheet
Bleached bristols
Cotton fiber writing paper
Unbl kraft packaging paper
Tissue
Wrapping
Shipping sack, unbl/bl sulfite
TOTAL PAPER PRODUCTS
Unbl kraft packaging paperboard
Semichemical paperboard
Recycled paperboard
Construction paper
Linerboard
Folding carton board
Milk carton board
Heavyweight cup/container
Plate, dish, and tray stock
Molded pulp products
TOTAL PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS
TOTAL ALL PRODUCTS
BaseX
836
4,678
181
325
0
41
6,062
625
88
169
122
47
41
30
21
9
42
1391
2,463
31
185
33
283
194
529
10
10
13
3,807
11,260
AX
-3
42
1
-13
0
9
35
-49
0
-7
-28
-2
-1
0
0
-5
-1
-95
-11
-1
-16
0
-4
-3
-1
0
0
0
-35
-95
%AX
*
+
*
-4.1
*
20.9
*
-7.8
*
-4.2
-22.9
-4.6
-2.6
*
*
-58.1
-1.9
-6.8
*
-1.6
-8.5
*
-1.3
-1.3
*
*
*
*
*
*
Base I
284
3,753
87
358
618
0
5,100
8,553
1304
774
0
59
596
239
121
2
2
11,811
165
118
165
189
12
12
12
12
12
19
743
17,654
AI
0
-6
0
3
3
0
0
7
0
12
0
0
2
0
0
1
0
26
0
0
2
0
0
1
0
0
0
0
5
31
*AI
*
*
*
1.0
*
*
*
*
*
1.5
*
*
*
*
*
26.0
1.1
*
*
+
1.5
*
1.4
6.1
*
3.1
1.9
*
*
*
X — export quantity I = import quantity A = "change in"
Totals and percent changes might not be exact because of rounding.
= less than 1%
5-38
-------
TABLE 5-29
FOREIGN TRADE QUANTITY ADJUSTMENTS (1989):
SELECTED PRODUCT CATEGORIES
Regulatory Alternative 26
(000 tons/yr)
Product Category
Special alpha and dissolving pulp
Bleached kraft <
Unbleached kraft
Bleached sulfite
Bleached secondary
Unbleached secondary
MARKET PULP TOTAL
Newsprint
Uncoated groundwood paper
Clay coated printing
Uncoated free sheet
Bleached bristols
Cotton fiber writing paper
Unbl kraft packaging paper
Tissue
Wrapping
Shipping sack, unbl/bl sulfite
TOTAL PAPER PRODUCTS
Unbl kraft packaging paperboard
Semichemical paperboard
Recycled paperboard
Construction paper
Linerboard
Folding carton board
Milk canon board
Heavyweight cup/container
Plate, dish, and tray stock
Molded pulp products
TOTAL PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS
TOTAL ALL PRODUCTS
BaseX
836
4,678
181
325
0
41
6,062
625
88
169
122
47
41
30
21
9
42
1,391
2,463
31
185
33
283
194
529
10
10
13
3,807
11.260
AX
-1
62
1
-13
0
9
58
-42
0
-7
-27
-2
-1
0
0
-5
-1
-87
-12
0
-16
0
-3
-3
-1
0
0
0
-34
-63
%AX
*
1.3
*
-3.9
*
21.1
1.0
-6.7
*
-4:0
-22.6
-4.5
-2.5
*
*
-57.4
-1.7
-6.3
*
*
-8.5
*
-1.1
-1.3
*
*
*
*
*
*
Base I
284
3,753
87
358
618
0
5,100
8^53
1304
774
0
59
596
239
121
2
2
11,811
165
118
165
189
12
12
12
12
12
19
743
17,654
AI
0
-9
-1
3
3
0
-4
6
0
11
0
0
2
0
0
1
0
24
0
0
2
0
0
1
0
0
0
0
5
25
%AI
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
1.4
*
*
*
*
*
25.5
1.0
*
*
*
1.5
*
1.2
6.1
*
3.1
1.9
*
*
*
X = export quantity I = import quantity A = "change in"
Totals and percent changes might not be exact because of rounding.
= less than 1%
5-39
-------
significant decline overall is for wrapping paper; the more stringent alternatives experience a
large 57 percent decline. However, wrapping paper contributes very little to the U.S. total export
value of pulp, paper, and paperboard products. Uncoated free sheet also experiences a notable
decline of 21 percent for the more stringent alternatives.
Import Value. Three product categories (bleached kraft, newsprint, and cotton fiber
writing paper) comprised more than 70 percent of total export value in 1989. None of these
categories is shown to be significantly affected by any of the regulatory alternatives. Of the
lesser valued products, the most notable changes in import value are the 6 percent increase for
folding carton board and the 28 percent increase in wrapping paper.
Import and Export Quantity. The results for import and export quantity generally mimic
the results for import and export value. The largest percent declines in export quantity occur for
wrapping paper and uncoated free sheet. The largest percent increases in import quantity occur
for wrapping paper and folding carton board.
5.2-3 Facility and Product Line Closures
The estimated number of pulp and paper facility closures and product line closures are
shown by facility type in Table 5-30. The more stringent alternatives are estimated to result in
11 possible mill closures and 14 total product-line closures. The majority of the closures occur at
paper or paperboard mills that buy market pulp to produce paper products.
5.2.4 Employment Impacts
The estimated employment impacts are shown in Tables 5-31 and 5-32. The market
impact model is capable of estimating employment changes in two ways. The first results from
facility closure, where all production and non-production employees at closure facilities are
dislocated. The second results from production level changes at facilities that continue
5-40
-------
9\
^
cn
CA
I
da
z
3
B
g
I
s
NH
U
s.
1
I
!i
o
p
p
=:
' i
*
Alternat
vo
El
i
§
Baseline
1— 1
O
O
M
CO
oo
o
5
«
oo
o
(S
c/l
t/3
0
U
T— (
en
oo
O
^
TH
«
oo
o
>o
cs
T— I
CO
oo
o
cs
<•— J
00
oo,
0?
VO
I
CO
Baseline
cs
cs
o
o
CO
U1
0,
o
VO
1
.
M
-,
.
o
a
Si
•M
•^
i
3
U
j
T— (
«
o\
o
s
«
o\
o
cs
T— 1
v»
o\
o
vo
(S
5-41
-------
o\
OO
OV
vK
Nn^
S
S
ea
s
3
TABLE 5-31
CTS: POTENT
<
Is
*•*
i
i
W)
ts
a
&
S
i— i
u
.S
t/1
a
n
-.
^C v^
*
^0t ^^
^»
*""5 ^9*
-^ ^
** «*5
*? ^
*- \A
< ^
S
(N
PO
, ,
(N
t/)
—
S
13
U
2
W)
o
c
f^
^
00
r>J
i
^^
t~
i
Ov
j^
-------
TABLE 5-32
EMPLOYMENT IMPACTS: POTENTIAL JOB CREATION
Facility Type
Pulp Mills
Paper/Paperboard Mills
Integrated Mills
Total
3
1
441
202
644
Regulatory
16
3
565
350
918
Alternative
23
3
565
308
876
24
3
571
307
881
25
3
570
303
876
26
3
570
300
873
5-43
-------
operations after regulation. Higher mill production levels require more production workers and
lower mill production levels require fewer workers.
Table 5-31 shows the estimated number of employees dislocated due to closure and
reduced production levels.4 The majority of job losses occur at integrated mills even though
paper or paperboard mills incur the majority of facility closures. This is because integrated mills
generally employ a greater number of employees than non-integrated mills.
Table 5-32 shows the estimated number of potential jobs created by increases in
production levels at some mills. This estimate assumes that the mills that increase output are
currently operating at their maximum worker-to-output ratio. To the extent they are not, the
number of potential jobs created may be less. The majority of the potential new jobs are created
at non-integrated paper or paperboard mills.
5.2.5 Consumer and Producer Surplus Changes
The estimated social welfare impacts as measured by changes in consumer and producer
surplus are shown in Tables 5-33 through 5-38. Because of higher prices and lower equilibrium
quantities consumed, both U.S. and foreign consumers experience losses in consumer surplus.
Because foreign producers increase output to U.S. markets in response to higher U.S. market
prices, foreign producers experience increases in producer surplus. U.S. producers generally
experience losses in producer surplus due to the reduced earnings that result from increased
pollution abatement costs.
For the more stringent regulatory alternatives, the majority of total welfare loss is
attributable to losses in U.S. consumer surplus. However, as the alternatives become more
stringent, U.S. producers share a greater portion of the total welfare loss burden because product
prices, and hence producer revenues, do not keep pace with the increases in regulatory
compliance costs.
*The estimates of baseline employment are discussed in Section 2.3 and Section 3.3.2.1.
5-44
-------
in
a
u
g*2
° - w
£4 2 ^^
^ 2 s
o 5 t.
Ill
P U) ^—'
en w
1"
en
3
e
H
So
a
I
•8
•**
as
3
&
a
(»
a
!
09
"5.
u
^
§
en
a
O
"**
1
|X^
*
D
.1
1
f.^
*
• M
&
O
CA
P
2L
t
•t!
^
*
*
c3
*
T— 1
O
^^
_n-
0-
•S
CD
^
*
*
CO
vd
*
"f
C5
t—<
VH
1
C«
TD
s
a*
u
a.
£
*
*
0
*
t
(—*,
.1— '
VI
o
3
T3
£
a-
T3
CS
0
^
"1
l^^
oo
CJ
H
1
vq
(S
T— 1
S3
1
*-H
^_J
^r
^*
a, I H
I
•a
r^ O
C-H l_
o ex
60 .
« 00
11
l!
51-
*8
o o
II II
5-45
-------
S
o
o
CO
eL
p ^
Q „ _
§11
5j 2*5
Q ^ u-
«> ?> o
Cc t? o
W o s
§'"
CO
z:
o
u
i
ss
s
w
1
5
1
en
"?•
CO
CO
h
V
a
3
c/i
a
o
U
J»
e
£
CO
P
J-hs
CO
a
OJD
"H
£
e
Ok
CU
Kl
en
cd
C3
oo
t3
-§
o
U
a.
oo
C5
o\
o
C5
en
en
o
S
i
•a
« CO
3D
•o
p
11
IS
^^
5-46
-------
CA
tn
1C)
S
1
a
o
CA
a,
o
5
SUMER
Z
O
u
4» /— v
> OS
- s
e» ^
S»-<
V*
« «-
5*
II
I1
V
«
"a
g
1
a
•M
«9
J3
S
S*
S
S
•o
£
ft-
'
3
f
CA
i
CA
a
o
O
t
1
1
CA
*~~1
1
1
CA
P
fl
OJD
*fi
b
•
CA
-j
fi
£
w
•e
£
ft.
*
*
CO
*
n
1-1
c^
PH
aj
"fe
^
*
*
06
^•^
*
o
oo
oo
(S
V.
O
3
•o
O
o
a.
CO
OH
*
*
OO
o
*
VO
i — i
i
as
rr
1
VI
o
3
•o
£
Ou,
•o
O
£1
o.
OH
VO
op
oo
o
T— 1
T-5
CO
oo
1
5
VO
oo
CO
1
>o
1
^
J^
1
H
52
u
u
T3
4-» .
SD
2
£•
•o a
W M
8 |
o-i
5-47
-------
VO
3
PS
a «,-,
25 S
P5 m 0\
OS &§
w 5 S
sl|
eo g}'~'
<£« fic
o
U
3
o
H
a
a
f^
6
z
'j§
s
en
S
3
H3
£
cu
.
«1
J3
"S,
3
en
5
3
a
y
^
a
.Sf>
en
i—^
.1
z
Jp
CO
a
oc
2
cS
CO
s.
'u
3
•O
£
a,
*
*
CO
i
*
CO
""•
£•
o
1
*
*
VO
CO
T-l
*
cs
oo
>o
S
rj-
0
Cu
k^
SJ
C.
ec
CV,
*
*
OO
o
*
t-;
t— t
i
(N
«n
*
•a
£
a.
c
IM
a.
C3
OH
C3
^^"
I
VO
O
T— (
S
CO
1
CM
vd
r— 1
0\
o
vq
r~^
oo
rr
1
15
8
TJ
«
oa
3D
is
c- 2
_. n!
t g
50 E
0
^ e-
"3 3
«•> 5>
1-s
5-48
-------
s
B
O *-
Is
VJ
o o
Zc
•—I
II II
5-49
-------
oo
in
3
CA
£
e
&
a
U
13
2
ca
a
f
CA
V
u
1
5
CO
f
3
CA
1*
H
3
a
a
!
b
CA
P
a
H
£
"3
P
a
Sr
g
£
CA
P
2,
r"*
1
•O
2
0,
*
*
T— 1
*
o\
VO
_Q.
p t
U
13
s
*
*
oq
T-H
*
°i
1
CO
oo
CO
o
T5
O
1—
CJ
n.
ca
IX
*
*
r-
C5
*
r- 3
I
vq
i
V)
O
TD
O
CU
•a
ca
O
^
a.
«
o
co
oo
i
oo
a\
oq
JS
op
T— (
o\
s
CO-
VO
o\
CO
1
1
£2
I
•a
« 00
a
3
o o
2,S
II I!
5-50
-------
5.3 RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN FINANCIAL MODEL AND MARKET MODEL RESULTS
The overall results of the financial and market models are consistent and complementary.
There are differences in the details, as expected from the differences in modeling assumptions
arid approaches (described in more detail in Section 3.4). Both models indicate minor declines
to domestic production levels in the range of 4 percent or less. Exports show a similar decline,
although the market model indicates that the declines may be concentrated in a small set of
product categories.
For Alternative 26, the models estimate that about 11 to 13 facilities will close. The
financial model contains the conservative assumption that no facility can pass the increased costs
of pollution control to purchasers through higher prices. The facilities that close with the
financial model, then, are the larger mills that incur the cost of process changes and air pollution
control requirements. The financial model estimates that 10,700 jobs are lost with the 13
closures. The market model assumes that incremental pollution control costs will be passed
through in accordance with what the market will bear. The closures projected by the market
model include smaller facilities that produce products with prices that do not increase enough to
offset the addition of pollution control costs, the changes in input prices, or reduced
consumption demand. The market model estimates nearly 2,800 job losses associated with the 11
facility closures and product line closures for these alternatives.
5.4 REFERENCES
CEA. 1993. Council of Economic Advisers. Economic report of the president. Washington,
DC. Table B-l.
DOL. 1992. Department of Labor. Monthly labor review 115(1 ):82. Washington, DC: U.S.
DOL, Bureau of Labor Statistics.
Pigler, Carmen C. 1993. RIMS multipliers for the- United States. Letter from Carmen C. Pigler,
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. Washington, D.C. to Maur.een F.
Kaplan, Eastern Research Group, Inc. Lexington. MA. 1 September.
5-51
-------
-------
SECTION SIX
SMALL BUSINESS IMPACTS
An analysis of impacts on small business entities was performed, in part, to comply with
the analysis requirements of the Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA) and to provide information on
how regulatory options affect small entities. The small business analysis focuses on whether
regulatory alternatives have undue or disproportionate impacts on small entities. Section 3.5
discusses various definitions for small entities.
Several definitions are used in this analysis. The financial model analysis uses a three-
tiered subdivision for both companies and facilities:
• Very small: 0 to 125 employees
• Small: 126 to 750 employees
» Large: More than 750 employees
The market model uses the same subdivisions plus a combination group of facilities and
companies with fewer than 750 employees.
6.1 FINANCIAL IMPACT ANALYSIS RESULTS
The impacts shown in Section 5.1 are split into size categories based on facility and
•»
company employment. The results are examined several ways—under costs for wastewater
treatment upgrades (BPT costs), under each BAT/PSES option (as applicable), and under each
regulatory alternative. The definitions for the options and regulatory alternatives are shown in
Section 4.1. In some cases, certain results are not reported in the summary tables because data
aggregation is inadequate to protect confidential business information. These results are
identified by "ND" (not disclosed) entries in the table.
V
6-1
-------
6.1.1 Impacts from BPT Costs
Tables 6-1 and 6-2 present the impacts from BPT costs on very small, small, and large
entities. Table 6-1 use? a facility basis for the categorization, and Table 6-2 uses a company basis
for the categorization. This pairing of tables is used throughout Section 6.1. The percentages
shown in each table refer to the percent of impact in the size category for that option and
parameter.1
Approximately 300 facilities are anticipated to incur costs of wastewater treatment
upgrades. The impacts do not change regardless of whether a facility basis or company basis is
used for the definition. One very small facility, which belongs to a very small company, is
projected to close under either option for wastewater treatment upgrades. Two small facilities
that belong to small companies also are projected to close under BPT Option 2. Three facilities
out of 300 represent only 1 percent of the entire population estimated to incur costs and only 0.5
percent of the entire population of pulp, paper, and paperboard facilities in the United States.
This is a very small overall percentage of closure, and the result that no large facilities close with
these costs is not indicative of undue impacts on small facilities or companies.
6.1.2 Impacts from BAT/PSES Costs
6.12.1 Dissolving Kraft
Since BAT/PSES costs are not projected to close facilities in the dissolving kraft
subcategory, there are no impacts projected for small facilities.
'For example, three facilities—two small and one very small—are projected to close under BPT
Option 2 (Tables 6-1 and 6-2). Of the closures. 33 percent are in the very small category and 67
percent are in the small category.
6-2
-------
TABLE 6-1
REGULATORY FLEXIBILITY ANALYSIS
BPT COSTS
FACILITY-LEVEL 1989 DATA
Category
Option 1
Option 2
Number of Mills
Count
Percent*
Closures
Count
Percent-
Count
Percent*
Very Small
Small
Large
Total
182
256
524
34.7%
48.9%
16.4%
100.0%
1 100.0%
0 0.0%
0 0.0%
1 100.0%
1 33.3%
2 66.7%
0 0.0%
3 33.3%
Number of Employees
Count Percent*
Loss in Employees**
Count
Percent* Count
Percent*
Very Small
Small
Large
Total
13.630
91.966
114,895
220.491
6.2%
41.7%
52.1%
100.0%
100 1000%
0 00%
0 0.0%
100 100.0%
100 9.1%
1000 90.9%
0 0.0%
1.100 100.0%
Shipments (Tons)
Count Percent*
Count
Loss in Shipment Tonnage
Percent* Count
Percent*
Very Small 4,919,637 5.7% 5,752 1000% 5.752 2.2%
Small 45,372.710 52.3% 0 00% 260.488 97.8%
Large 36,419,405 42.0% 0 0.0% 0 00%
Total 86,711,752 100.0% 5,752 1000% 266.240 2.2%
Shipments ($000)
Count
Percent*
Loss in Shipments ($000)
Count
Percent"
Count
Percent*
Very Small $2,521,977 4.3%
Small $26,412,033 45.1%
Large $29.595.176 50.6%
Total $58.529,186 100.0%
$13.026 1000% $13.026 6.0%
$0 00% $203.586 940%
SO 00% SO 00%
$13.026 1000% $216.612 60%
Export ($000)
Very Small
Small
Large
Total
Count
$99.493
$2.891.979
$2.862.478
$5.853.950
Percent*
17%
494%
489%
100.0%
Loss in Exports ($000)
Count
$966
$0
$0
$966
Percent'
1000%
00%
00%
1000%
Count
$966
$633
SO
$1.599
Percent*
604%
396%
00%
1000%
Note:
(*) Percent of impact in size category
(H Rounded to nearest 100 employees
6-3
-------
TABLE 6-2
REGULATORY FLEXIBILITY ANALYSIS
•TT COSTS-
COMPANY-LEVEL 1989 DATA
Cataeoiy
Option 1
Option 2
Number of Mills
Count
Percent*
Closures
Count
Percent-
Count
Percent*
Very Small
Small
Large
Total
63 32.1%
83 42,3%
50 25.5%
196 100.0%
1 100.0%
0 0.0%
0 0.0%
1 100.0%
1 33.3%
2 66.7%
0 0.0%
3 100.0%
Number of Employees
Count Percent*
Loss in Employees**
Count
Percent* Count
Percent*
Very Small
Small
La roc
Total
4.197 1.9%
27.010 12.2%
189.284 85.8%
220.491 100.0%
100 100.0% 100 9.1%
0 00% 1000 90.9%
0 0.0% 0 0.0%
100 100,0% 1.100 100.0%
Shipments (Tons)
Count Percent*
Loss in Shipment Tonnage
Count Percent* Count Percent*
V«y Smalt
Small
ToUl
1.361.956 1.6%
9.369.963 10.8%
75.979.833 87.6%
86.711.752 100,0%
5,752 100.0% 5.752 2.2%
0 0.0% 260.488 97.8%
0 00% 0 0.0%
5,752 100.0% 266.240 100.0%
Shipments (SOOO)
Count
Percent*
Loss in Shipments ($000)
Count
Percent* Count
Percent*
Very Small $695.040 1.2%
Small S5.748.242 98%
Laroe $52.065.904 89 0%
Total $58.529.186 1000%
S13.026 1000% S13.026 6.0%
SO 00% $203.586 940%
$0 00% SO 00%
S13.026 1000% 5216.612 1000%
Export (SOOO)
Count Percent*
Loss in Exports (SOOO)
Count
Percent* Count
Percent*
Very Small $39.508 07%
Small $756,824 129%
Laroe $5.057.618 864%
Total $5.853.950 100 0%
$966 1000% $966 604%
$0 00% $633 396%
SO 00% SO 00%
$966 1000% $1.599 1000%
Note
(*) Percent of impact in size cateoory
(**) Rounded to nearest 100 employees
6-4
-------
6.12.2 Dissolving Suffite
Tables 6-3 and 6-4 are an outline of the impacts of process change costs for dissolving
sulfite facilities and companies. The impacts associated with closures of dissolving sulfite
facilities are not reported to protect confidential data. The overall loss in shipments for this
subcategory is less than 0.5 percent of total industry shipments and about 3 percent of total
exports.
6.12.3 Bleached Papergrade Kraft and Soda
Tables 6-5 and 6-6 list the impacts for facilities and companies in the bleached
papergrade kraft and soda subcategory. For Option 1, the mill closures are evenly split between
small and large facilities and companies. Large entities (both facilities and companies), however,
experience 80 percent or more of the loss in employees, shipments (tonnage and value), and
exports. For Option 2, two-thirds of the closures and 80 percent or more of the losses belong to
the large facilities and companies. For Options 3 and 4, there is an additional closure, which is a
small facility that belongs to a large company. Large entities, by either definition, experience a
disproportionate share of the impacts. For Option 5, on a facility basis, the large entities have:
• 16 percent of the facilities, 78 percent of the closures
• 50 percent of the employees, 90 percent of the job losses
• 40 to 50 percent of shipments and exports, 70 to 90 percent of the losses
On a company basis, large entities bear the larger impacts (90 to 96 percent of the losses).
6-5
-------
TABLE SO
REGULATORY FLEXIBILITY ANALYSIS
BAT/PSES PROCESS CHANGE COSTS: DISSOLVING SULFITE
FACILITY-LEVEL 1083 DATA
Cat»flory
Option 1
Option 2
Number of Mills
Very Small
Small
La roe
Total
VwySmaB
Small
Uige
Total
Very Small
Small
Large
Total
Very Small
Smart
Large
Total
Very Small
Smal
La rpc
Total
Court
182
256
66
524
Percent*
34.7%
48.9%
16.4%
100.0%
Number of Employees
Count
13.630
91.966
114.895
220.491
Percent*
6.2%
41.7%
52.1%
100.0%
Shipments (Tons)
Count
4.919.637
45.372.710
36.419.405
86.711.752
Percent*
5,7%
52.3%
42.0%
100,0%
Shipments (SOOO)
Count
S2.521.977
$26.412.033
S29.595.176
S58.529.186
Percent*
4,3%
451%
506%
1000%
Export (SOOO)
Count
$99.493
S2.891.979
S2.862.478
S5.853.950
Percent*
17%
494%
48.9%
1000%
Closures
Count Percent* Count
ND NO
ND ND
ND ND
1 100.0%
Percent*
ND ND
ND ND
ND ND
2 100.0%
Loss in Employees"
Count Percent* Count
ND ND
ND ND
ND ND
ND 100.0%'
Percent*
ND ND
ND ND
ND ND
ND 100.0%
Loss in Shipment Tonnaoe
Count Percent* Count
ND ND
ND ND
ND ND
ND 100 0%
Loss in Shipments (SOOO)
Count Percent* Count
ND ND
NO ND
ND ND
ND 1000%
Percent*
ND ND
ND ND
ND ND
ND 100,0%
Percent*
ND ND
ND ND
ND ND
ND 1000%
Loss in Exports (SOOO)
Count Percent* Count
ND ND
ND ND
ND ND
ND 100 0%
Percent*
ND ND
ND ND
ND ND
ND 1000%
Note
Rounded to nearest 100 employees
6-6
-------
TABLE 6-4
REGULATORY FLEXIBILITY ANALYSIS
BAT/PSES PROCESS CHANGE COSTS: DISSOLVING SULRTE
COMPANY-LEVEL 1989 DATA
Category
Option 1
Option 2
Number of Mills
Count
Percent*
Closures
Count
Percent*
Count
Percent*
Very Small
Small
Large
Total
63
83
50
196
32.1%
42,3%
25.5%
100.0%
ND ND
ND ND
ND ND
1 100,0%
ND ND
ND ND
ND ND
2 100.0%
Number of Employees
Loss in Employees*'
Count
Percent*
Count
Percent*
Count
Percent*
Very Small
Small
Large
Total
4,197
27,010
189,284
220,491
1.9%
12.2%
85.8%
100.0%
ND ND
ND ND
ND ND
ND 100.0%
ND ND
ND ND
ND ND
ND 100.0%
Shipments (Tons)
Loss In Shipment Tonnage
Percent*
Count
Percent*
Very Small
Small
Large
Total
1,361,956
9.369.963
75,979,833
86,711.752
1.6%
10.8%
87.6%
100.0%
ND ND
ND ND
ND ND
ND 1000%
ND ND
ND ND
ND ND
ND 100.0%
Shipments ($000)
Count
Percent*
Loss in Shipments ($000)
Count
Percent*
Count
Percent*
Very Small $695.040 1.2%
Small $5,748.242 9.8%
Large $52.085,904 89 0%
Total $58.529.186 100.0%
ND ND
ND ND
ND ND
ND 100 0%
ND ND
ND ND
ND ND
ND 100,0%
Export (SOOO)
Loss in Exports (SOOO)
Percent*
Count
Percent'
Count
Percent*
Very Small $39.508 0.7%
Small $756.824 12.9%
Large $5.057.618 86 4%
Total $5.853.950 100 0%
ND ND
ND ND
ND ND
ND 100 0%
ND ND
ND ND
ND ND
ND 100 0%
Note
(*) Percent of impact in size category
(~) Rounded to nearest 100 employees
6-7
-------
o
!§°
isi
* >rao(Q
C £ a 75
=
! i
;"ss
r CM to
O ^ (D O
O> fM O)
5 f> 5
'
£
SCO O CO
5 iQ ic
CO tO Ol
|as
** o
8t
O tp CO Q
O) O
8lO O) 3!
CN r^- c3
in to CM
gggg
°°88
tfti
gggg
°°'8S
88SS
CM CN
If
88S
CB ro
m 15
""
«~r
6-8
-------
§
8
Q
I
t
S
S
£ p
r* <» r>i
§>-
—I
origg
«-" (N fO"
588
o ^- o> p
o C3 oj s;
££8
i E ^i
O CO t
S_
gggg
°°'88
SS
gggg
gggg
°°88
S83S
CM
-------
6.12.4 Papergrade Sulfite
Tables 6-7 and 6-8 list the impacts for facilities and companies in the papergrade sulfite
subcategory. On a facility basis, under Option 1, small entities have more closures and larger
losses of export revenues, but smaller impacts in the loss of jobs, total shipment tonnage, and
total shipment value. Option 2 has larger impacts on large facilities (although the details are not
reported). On a company level, large entities bear a greater proportion of impacts, although the
details are not reported in Table 6-8.
6.12.5 Unbleached Papergrade Kraft, Semichemical, and Nonwood Chemical
No closures are projected for the costs associated with the options for these
subcategories. There are therefore no impacts on small facilities or companies.
6.13 Impacts from Regulatory Alternative Costs
Tables 6-9 and 6-10 list the impacts for the regulatory alternatives. The impacts for the
regulatory alternatives cluster into four groups based on the number of projected mill closures.
For Alternatives 2 through 5, the impacts generally fall on small facilities that are owned
by large companies. With the exception of the loss in exports (where losses occur only for the
large companies), the impacts look roughly proportional to the distribution of closures. Given
the small number of closures (three of approximately 300 facilities), the distribution shows no
clustering by size category.
The three remaining groups of alternatives have 13 to 15 projected mill closures. The
distribution of these projected closures among the size categories is comparable for Alternatives
11 through 26. There appear to be no disproportionate impacts on smaller facilities or
companies. Very small facilities and companies show proportionately fewer impacts than other
size entities.
6-10
-------
TABLE 6-7
REGULATORY FLEXIBILITY ANALYSIS
BAT/PSES PROCESS CHANGE COSTS: PAPERORADE SULFITE
FACILITY-LEVEL 1989 DATA
Category
Option 1
Option 2
Number of Mills
Count
Percent*
Closures
Count
Percent*
Count
Percent*
Very Small
Small
Large
Total
182
256
86
524
34.7%
48.9%
16.4%
100.0%
0 0.0%
3 60.0%
2 40.0%
5 100.0%
0 0.0%
1 33.0%
2 66.7%
3 100.0%
Number of Em
Count
ployees
Percent*
Loss in Employees**
Count
Percent*
Count
Percent*
Very Small 13,630 6.2% 0 0.0% 0 0.0%
Small 91.966 41.7% 1,700 43.6% ND ND
Large 114,895 52.1% 2,100 538% ND ND
Total 220,491 100.0% 3,900 100.0% 2.600 100.0%
Shipments (Tons)
Count Percent*
Loss in Shipment Tonnage
Count
Percent* Count Percent*
Very Small 4,919.637 5.7% 0 0.0% 0 0.0%
Small 45.372.710 52.3% 357,026 45.1% ND ND
Large 36.419.405 42.0% 434,574 54.9% ND ND
Total 86.711.752 100.0% 791.600 100.0% 506.535 1000%
Shipments ($000)
Count Percent*
Loss in Shipments ($000)
Count
Percent* Count
Percent*
Very Small $2.521.977
Small $26.412.033
Large $29.595.176
Total $58.529.186
4.3% $0
45.1% $366.062
506% $400.729
100.0% $766,791
0.0% $0 00%
47.7% ND ND
523% ND ND
1OO.O% $475.372 100 0%
Very Small
Small
Large
Total
Export ($000)
Count
$99.493
$2.891.979
$2.862,478
$5.853.950
Percent*
1 7%
494%
489%
1000%
Loss in Exports ($000)
Count
$0
$2.207
$1
405
$3.612
Percent*
00%
61 1%
389%
1000%
Count
$0
ND
ND
$1.405
Percent*
00%
ND
ND
1000%
Note
(*) Percent of impact in size category
(**) Rounded to nearest 100 employees
6-11
-------
TABLE 6-8
REGULATORY FLEXIBILITY ANALYSIS
BAT/PSES PROCESS CHANGE COSTS: PAPERGRADE SULFITE
COMPANY-LEVEL 1969 DATA
category
Option 1 |
Number of Mills
Very Small
Small
Large
Tout
Count
182
256
86
524
Percent*
34.7%
48.9%
16.4%
100.0%
Number at Employees
Very Small
Small
La roc
ToUl
Very Small
Small
Uige
ToUl
Very Small
Small
Large
ToUl
Count
13.630
91.966
114.895
220,491
Percent*
6.2%
41.7%
52.1%
100.0%
Shipments (Tons)
Count
4.919.637
45.372.710
36.419.405
86.711.752
Percent*
5.7%
52.3%
42.0%
100.0%
Shipments ($000)
Count
S2.521.977
S26.412.033
S29.595.176
S58.529.186
Percent*
4,3%
45.1%
50.6%
100,0%
Export ($000)
VetySmail
Small
Large
Total
Count
S99.493
52.891^979
S2.862.478
SS.853.950
Percent*
1,7%
494%
489%
1000%
Option 2
Closures
Count
0
ND
ND
5
Percent*
0.0%
ND
ND
100.0%
Count
0
ND
ND
3
Percent*
0.0%
• ND
ND
100.0%
Loss in Employees"
Count
0
ND
ND
3.900
Percent*
0,0%
ND
ND
100,0%
Loss in Shipment
Count
0
ND
ND
791.600
Percent*
00%
ND
ND
1000%
Count
0
ND
ND
2,600
Tonnage
Count
0
ND
ND
506.535
Percent*
0.0%
ND
ND
100.0%
Percent*
00%
ND
ND
100.0%
Loss in Shipments ($000)
Count
SO
ND
ND
S766.791
Percent'
00%
ND
ND
1000%
Count
SO
ND
ND
$475.372
Percent*
0.0%
ND
ND
1000%
Loss in Exports ($000)
Count
$0
ND
ND
S3.612
Percent*
00%
ND
ND
1000%
Count
SO
ND
ND
$1.405
Percent*
00%
ND
ND
1000%
Note
{*) Percent of impact in size category
("^ Rounded to nearest 100 employees.
6-12
-------
-
:
-
1
-
1
< *>
III
ij 1- *"
£32
|||
r- in co o
; ^588
*- CO ^ tO
r- o co o
"838
*- o> in in
| I
Q *- CO tO O c
« r^ ^r eo o ~
•g to CN o g
-
*~ °* "*" ^
8
o o o o
~ ° 8 ° 8
1
O CO O CO
•g
£ r«- o> <•* o
w-
S IN (D to in i p x
_
^r to" *-*
5
°|°8
s
0
3
i s';;g
I "°'
«
*r ro *-".-v' p f.
C T- Ol •- fN IT
j2
CN CO O S
°KS8
SI8S
g "Ifi'i
i
CN O» O O
S*" «—
^
«§§s
m" ^^52 ?
| I?S f
CN ^ ^T O ^
5 '- j
g8||
o W «-" co"
gggg
I °8°3
i
°s°s
to to
^ CO CO
• r^ CO £ E
ll " * " :
S°§K
to P^ ^ f*-
•g O) CN O> «-* j
g o> CO ^ r*-
Q -V* lO tf? g"
in CN CN p
1 °5S§
o
co" g" eo" cp
"s'is"
^r o in o
= °'?558
!
to co r- CN
g in v in m_
O £^" JQ S S
"
ggsg
*~
S"5|"
CO ID CN p
!
|8S8
•* S S i^
1 88
i S5S|
S!
I 8*8
8
P p p p
c
8SS&
E S S
i 'in
sgsg
3 H S m CD
O £A ^ <^
ill! Ilii till fill lit!
If
M
Q. 2
.i2
*i
||
^o:
cC
5
6-13
-------
XXX*
r^ in cq co
*• S 5? 8
E
£
|
|
i
»-i^ *- o
''
!
:a£
ito
»- com O
CN CN If) O
0 -w rsi O
SSRS
S
8*
o o> oi Q
*- r^. o
§!§§
CN CO" O"
XXX*
CM CD
° 2 g 8
88§8
** a?
O oo r-
co" Q CN" to"
) in h*
O I1*-
eo T-; 55
«- oo O
p *-t O) p
O O> C3 Q
CN r*- o
8 CN S 8
co" in"o>"
co co r-
* co" T-" in"
p p o o
°°8'8
«8
l rl
> u> _j i- xoJjii:
> 03 J3
O CN T- I
K CO tO (
gi" (p" r^." (
QS8!
its
if
.s§
.so
6-14
-------
On a facility basis, large facilities account for 16 percent of the population, but about
one-third of the closures. Large facilities account for nearly half of the jobs, shipments, and
exports, and bear about half the impacts in job loss and loss in shipment tonnage and value.
Small facilities show higher proportional impacts in the loss of export revenues.
On a company basis, large companies form about 25 percent of the population. They
bear 50 to 60 percent of the impacts in terms of the number of closures. Large companies
account for approximately 80 to 90 percent of the number of employees and shipments in the
industry population; impacts to large companies account for about 80 percent of the losses for
these parameters. Large companies incur 40 to 70 percent of the loss in exports, depending on
the alternative.
Tables 6-11 through 6-14 summarize the results of the financial ratio analysis at the
facility level. Table 6-11 has all mills in the analysis; results for very small, small, and large
facilities are shown in Tables 6-12 through 6-14. Large facilities show greater impacts in their
financial ratios than either the small or very small facilities.
Tables 6-15 through 6-18 list the financial ratio analysis on a company basis. Based on
the average change in financial ratios, very small companies show the greatest impact for
Alternatives 5 though 26. Mean values, however, are sensitive to outliers and there is one
closure in the very small category. Hence, the larger impacts seen for the average change in
i
financial ratios can be a reflection of the single closure. Median values are more representative
of the impacts to "typical" facilities. The median change in financial ratios for very small
companies is generally well within the range seen for the business cycle. The exception is net
working capital-to-total assets. Regulatory costs can affect this ratio by reducing the numerator
(net working capital) and increasing the denominator (total assets). The fluctuation in this ratio
could indicate that very small firms are likely to need sources of money other than or in addition
to working capital to finance the pollution control expenditures.
Based on the median change in financial ratios, large companies are projected to incur
more significant financial impact than small companies. This result is consistent with the data
6-15
-------
1
4 td
3 Is
§
*!
s
to
tz
O »"* O> O *~ if)
tijj cji W r^ P T
t0 CO CO tO OJ O)
^ CO ** CM in CO
l CM i*p" CD" ^-'
coco
'-i—
O4 C-J CO CM *- CO COCO IO CO
O> v CO O> ^"^ ^ CO COCO
in CM Wt^i *YT tbcM o"*r-
CO v— tO CO
UJ Csl *^ eo *- p
4W ,- CD-
CMCM lO
seae
COCO
SS gg SS Jfg SS
v- O CM CD (MO CO CO CO U1
COCO O) O) COO) TO O> tO
TCD ^P ^P *? *9 (?u?
^^ in»- eo to coco
S CO S S ^~ 2 CM
as
**
9 2
f
Si
5
g
cr
•E
*
H
1
£ E
cs
(0 W
iH
ill
s
6-16
-------
^
I
s
e
£
is
?T "TV
v r~ 10 •*
cst- 1^10 Tr-; 10 •»
•79 <4-i "TV <9<9
com
CM r^ r^ in
CM l>- I-- 10
XX
1O •»
oico
CM r^- r^ 10
10 *r 1O1O
CO
10 *r in if)
<9 - IO^T 1010
•79 "7T T'T «?«? 9"
gg gg gg gg gg.
do do do do do
gg gg gg gg gg
do do dd do do
• o o °, °. "^ °.°, So
do do od do oo
gg gg gg gg gg
oo od oo oo oo
5* XX XX
I)
-------
t- u.t
cq r*» co p
TV °'<9
m co CM c
up" tf jf «
?T ^<9
CM CO CO O
Up ^' O CO"
gg
XX XX XX
CN CO CO CN CO V
XX XX XX
o> CN *- *«r r-. ^~
8CN CN CO
. v fy
gg
XX XX
CO CM I*- T
?T °°?
ex xx
>r- •fl'CM
K °«?
c5 up
XX XX
co in co co
XX XX XX
5)CM COCO <^CN
?? J?E?
ieac aeac
in o CN CN
XX
CO CO
XX
CM CO
XX
^ae iE#
co ^; eq *-
CO *7 CN W
XX
-
g
XX
en en
XX
v- €O
in co
•79
t^ ^^ ^se
) T- (O O> tp CO
) *7 ^9 °* *9
tn co o o
gg
XX
CO CO
1*7 CN<^ OT<9 t^> co
tor*. »n»-
!£ 8S gfi
CN r^.
CO r- fNto CN«- . ,. m
-------
2
I
S
i
i
z
Id
» $3
J =5<3
m o o:
i
e
c
g
1
?
£
1
I
dine Parameter
I
CD
CN
±2
CM
S
CM
CN
5
CD
±±
i
CO
tr
*-
±±
in
S
i
±s
CM
j1
i
.s
1
r^ o> *- co
X* X*
O in o o> v <
W in co in d o> co *-" eo' in
*T ' T V V ' *«* ^ ^ •
co in o oi co «-
o in oo i- (N in
na
cooi I--CM tnoi COCM tnco
p co co o> co in f*", T °,in.
O ^ F"- CO O> f*- O GO 5> o S
as
"
-------
w
|
5
S
£
-1
1
2
1
TABLE «-16
COMPAHY-tEVEt f
AU. COMPANIES
|
1
_s
i
£
i
~
I
1
I
-
I
|
I
1
1
g
i
^
S
1
<
1
CO
ft£
T-
(O
§
<
£
c
^
i
rt
5
*
en
s
g
*"
m
I
£
S
g
|
5
~£ *£ 4 4 *Jf iC £ dS ^£ f£ ^ S? J* «P
C4co T-CO ^ o* to to o o* en to c* to
Giro" ^co- c>iW in- rir ^^f Wo?
** *# ## ff ## #3? *#
d cy^ ir hj CM" W in r-' CM jf 19" 'f j; r~
•^•co coo ICM t*.co T-CO y;1^: <°. ^
Off JT ^' CM' if in r- CM £ «?•<(• »; Op
CMCO T-CO ^*CM coin rocN oco CNin
OC, ?, «J,V UOT- T^T. ,9^. T;CO
CMCO T-r*- *TCM coin COCM .roco CM^T
d co' v oy CN" T- in T-' »q jf 'f f' j; "cp
** ** #* #* ** ** **
CM r^- wo ^CN h»to cNf^ o>t^ eoh»
o <7 T" c^> ri ^* ui T^ ' cj r ^ *f r *9
OT o>w coo* critp oj«- tfiv- T-r- T T *" *9
*7 T ' ' ^T T
OJT h«-r- COCN IOiO IOCN VCD OT
cri <7 eo a? cji «7 « *- j^ ^ Y T JI °?
cn-c1 h-r- OCN into mo* vto o^
eft e? P> <9 ey »7 10 *-' ^ W ^ f ^ <9
*/: ^dc ^# # # ## ^ :P # #
lOO O(O IOO OJO r*O O)'T ^TCS
Cf o cyo eyes oo (90 «^ «7 ' W oi
#* *# ## ## ## #!P ##
cyo ojo' ^*° oo 190 v*? *r*r
Jf #: ^d! * * # # # # # ;P ^ #
»-O o oo tocn toco
torjeneo io«(O *-
^^ tfe^c ° ^ # ^ 0V~ S*** f f
V. toco
•n tf^ 0 r- «- <-
** i
S* SS w^ ££ gS 5S JS
SS ^!^ 52?
cc cc cc cc cc o'o' cc
a| 3| aj a| a | §g z|
{I,!!11!
| | 1 ! i 1 i
i
i
i
§
6-20
-------
w
1
!
is
ii
gi
&H
* ii
2 Ii
f 8S
"•
5
g
i
6
Q.
z
=
1
i
s
g
£
|
=
§
E
R
R
R
i
1
E
a.
|
I
g
i
„.
fc*
"*
r>
3
S
00
*~
tfi
'
1
.i
1
«
0) o o> co 5T h* r*» o *- *- ^1 P *P ^
W *ar iri t*» rt ^— oo *~ jo cp cji o i** ^
*£ "f ^C ^ ^ £ ££ dC^ ^ dS d! JE
5? p 5? £5 34 3§ S5
O) O O> CO ^T t^ h* O v *~ ^ O (D TT
^^f *>T o roco 'O-r^. N-O ^^ ^ro Ol O f** CO
*? *? ' ' ' *? ' TV
^ ^ :£:£ £^ ^ ^ ^ ^ rf rf d?c£
O> O O> o O)co -vr** h-o ^-^- TO n^Q JN^ >^«> 5S ™!Q 50°*
CN
## ## ^0 ff ar> jr- ##
oa> CM«- ceo CM»- too* »-eo pjf; 'r*
tfj^T O)O> *^*C (N*^ ^^
(O tf> ^ f^ CN
## # Jt *- CM #/ « CO 0 •- ##
coco coo *HCN aoo) 2*** *-o i*> »•
CD CM (O (O *~ ^ r« y-' CJ> O
~ in to ^^ ^ CM rt
!| If !j !| l| || ji
c . e 1 1 i i |
| | 2 1 5 }sl *
| | { 1 i ! 1
I
3
p
1
6-21
-------
\t
d
uj
1
I
£
i
1
1
15
-
t
[
i
i
i
^
§
§
GO
i
I
to
*?
T"
S*"
£
i
i
CN
5
X
o>
i
i
in
i
e
1
Variation
XX XX XX XX XX XX XX
O CO N. CO CN *• OT r- t- i- T CN O>
T. C9e? t?t? *" *~ JjJ"? V J2 "} *?
XX XX XX XX XX XX XX
COCO OCN CO f*- T-CN Ol 1*. *- «- TO»
T i °! T cfff *° *~ j;j •? V J2 ^ *5"
XX XX XX XX XX XX XX
r- to CO CN d f- OCS T- r- *- CO CN O»
^tf COT CN9 »r .j, T? ,,5,
O tO tO CO CN IS* O CN O) f»* •*— V ^ O>
i • i • i~ cji * *T
p <0 (DO N 1*. 0) 01 0) N; T- to WCN T-.V OCN or- oo> *-o>
17 i
^tf: ^dt XX XX XX XX 'XX
coco TCO v-r*- 01 CN co i>- o m oo>
^c, ,9
co° cji co" co' CN' 9 in »- o' cp T- co" to' cji
XX XX XX XX XX XX XX
too coo mo CMO coo coco co«-
cji c> T' o 9 o' v- o co o 9 i o' «-' o' 117 o 9 IT" ^ W
X^s XX XX XX XX XX XX
COO COO TO OO COO CNO CNi-
coo coo 90 i-o ino cyco «^ «^
XX XX XX XX XX XX XX
COO COO TO OO COO CNIO CN«-
eoo coo 9 o -«-o ino *?*? VT'
XX XX XX XX XX XX XX
COT ^o*", r*.co coco t^eo cor^ P10.
XX XX N0 XX « •* g fc XX
TCM COh- CNCN OCN CDIO J^O «O ""
-- *-> fi S - gg- «;=
*# XX ™*- XX «>^ r:£ XX
*r*o O) o 55*° S
-------
2
58
. §1
iu PUI
_J = O
M 2 Q;
£ 83
o in
•Y"?
CO CN
Of Of
n cp'
CN r-. O) to
co" ^ oi IY
CN (p
to'^
o> to
oi oi
OU> (OCN
to o>
CO CO
*- CO
to in
O)O coco
O) O
co oi
CON- O*O
"TCO OOr-
O) O
to" oi
o> p
co CN
OCO COO)
CN<
tp co
T^ CO
a? c?
(N CD
Oi »-'
OU> OlO
io q
«?T'
q
CN o
Oi^r ^r^- *-CN ON.
-<° gs? SS 8£
O<£) CO «-
p
m
S - <
o:
5
•s
6-23
I
-------
that large facilities with chemical pulping operations bear a substantial portion of the cost of
pollution control.
6.2 MARKET IMPACT ANALYSIS RESULTS
Given the similarity of results seen with the financial model analysis and market model
analysis of impacts in Section Five, the market model analysis for this section focuses on
Regulatory Alternative 26.
6.2.1 Facility-Level Results
6.2.1.1 Closure Distribution
Facility closures associated with regulating the industry are estimated by the market
impact model for each size category. Table 6-19 shows that just over 2 percent of the facilities in
the small combination group are predicted to close due to regulation, while just over 1 percent of
i
the facilities in the.large combination group discontinue operations. Within the small
combination group, facility closures are almost evenly divided across the small and very small
subgroups. Of those facilities projected to close by the market impact model, almost two-thirds
are independently owned and operated with the remaining one-third part of a multifacility group.
6.2.13 Employment Changes
Production and non-production worker employment changes associated with regulating
the industry are also estimated by the market impact model. The changes in employment result
from both mill closures and production changes at mills continuing to operate with the
regulations. Table 6-20 shows that small combination group facilities, as a whole, incur a 0.9
percent loss in employment due to regulation, while large facilities are also predicted to lose less
than 1 percent of their employment. Within the small combination category, small facilities are
6-24
-------
TABLE 6-19
CLOSURES OF INDEPENDENT AND MULTIFACHITY MILLS BY SIZE: VALUES WITH
REGULATORY ALTERNATIVE 26
Size based
on employment
Small
Combination
Group (<750)
Small (<750 &
>125)
Very Small (j<125)
Large (>750)
Total
Independently Owned
Number
4
1
3
0
4
Percent
Change
-4.2
-2.3
-6.0
0.0
-4.1
Multifacility
Group
Percent
Number Change
6
3
3
1
7
-1.5
-1.4
,
-1.8
-1.2
-1.5
Total
Number
10
4
6
1
11
Percent
Change
-2.1
-1.5
-2.7
-1.2
-1.9
6-25
-------
TABLE 6-20
CHANGES IN EMPLOYMENT OF INDEPENDENT AND MULTIFACILTTY MILLS BY SIZE:
VALUES WITH
REGULATORY ALTERNATIVE 26
Size based
on employment
Small Combination
Group (<750)
Small (<750 &
>125)
Very Small (<125)
Large (>750)
Total
Independently
Owned
Number
-273
-237
-37
2
-271
Percent
Change
-1.5
-1.6
-1.1
0.1
-1.3
Multifacility
Group,
Percent
Number Change
-647
-652
5
-984
-1,631
-0.7
-0.9
-0.0
-0.9
-0.8
Total
Number
-921
-889
-32
-982
-1,902
Percent
Change
-0.9
-1.0
-0.2
-0.9
-0.9
6-26
-------
predicted to lose 1 percent of their baseline employment, but very small facilities only incur a
loss of 0.2 percent. The largest employment loss, over 50 percent of the predicted decline, is
realized by large facilities that are part of a multifacility group, while large independently owned
and operated facilities, as a group, realize a slight net increase in employment.
6.2.1.3 Product Revenues, Total Costs of Production, and EBIDT
Additional indicators of the severity of the economic impact on small facilities include the
changes in product revenues, total costs of production, and EBIDT as estimated by the market
impact model. Table 6-21 provides the changes in facility-level revenues, costs, and EBIDT by
size, for mills that continue to operate with the regulation.
6.2.1.4 Annual Compliance Costs
The relative severity of the regulations can also be measured by comparing the ratios of
annual compliance costs to total revenues, total costs, and EBIDT across small and large
facilities. Table 6-22 shows the ratio of facility-level annual compliance costs to total revenues,
total costs, and EBIDT by size, for facilities that continue to operate after regulation.
6.2.2 Company-Level Results
6.22.1 Closure Distribution
The distribution of facility closures across small and large firms is presented in
Table 6-23. The absolute number of facility closures estimated by the market impact model is
almost evenly split across small and large firms with 6 facilities closing that are owned by small
firms and 5 facility closures for large firms. In terms of percentage change from baseline, small
firms incur two times the facility closures of large firms—a 2.8 percent loss at small firms versus
a 1.4 percent loss at large firms.
6-27
-------
TABLE 6-21
CHANGES IN FACILITY-LEVEL REVENUES, COSTS,
AND EBIDT BY SIZE: VALUES WITH
REGULATORY ALTERNATIVE 26
Facility size based on employment
Small Combination Group (<750)
Mean
Minimum
Maximum
Small (<750 & >125)
Mean
Minimum
Maximum
Very Small (<125)
Mean
Minimum
Maximum
Large (>750)
Mean
Minimum
Maximum
Total
Mean
Minimum
Maximum
Percentage
Total
revenues
2.4
-11.4
118.2
2.4
-11.4
118.2
0.8
-3.8
8.0
1.2
-1.0
17.4
2.1
-11.4
118.2
change
Total
costs
11.5
-7.8
3,940.9
11.8
-7.8
3,940.9
1.5
-2.2
7.9
2.6
-0.1
20.6
9.6
-7.8
3,940.9
EBDOT
6.5
-99.8
296.2
6.7
-99.8
296.2
-0.6
-37.0
44.8
-2.3
-28.0
35.8
4.7
-99.8
296.2
'Earnings before interest, depreciation, and taxes.
6-28
-------
TABLE 6-22
RATIO OF FACILITY-LEVEL ANNUAL COMPLIANCE COSTS TO TOTAL REVENUES,
TOTAL COSTS, AND EBIDT BY SIZE:
VALUES WITH REGULATORY ALTERNATIVE 26
Facility size based on employment
Small Combination Group (<750)
Mean
Minimum
Maximum
Small (<750 & >125)
Mean
Minimum
Maximum
Very Small (^125)
Mean
Minimum
Maximum
Large (>750) '
Mean
•Minimum
Maximum
Total
Mean
Minimum
Maximum
Ratio of annual
Total
revenues
0.5
-0.2
15.5
0.5
-0.2
15.5
0.7
0.0
5.0
1.4
0.0
5.4
0.7
-0.2
15.5
compliance
Total
costs
0.7
-0.3
25.5
0.7
-0.3
25.5
0.9
0.0
7.3
2.0
0.0
7.4
1.0
-0.3
25.5
costs to
EBIDT1
4.1
-1.7
324.3
4.0
-1.7
324.3
6.9
0.0
74.3
6.8
0.0
53.5
4.5
-1.7
324.3
'Earnings before interest, depreciation, and taxes.
6-29
-------
TABLE 6-23
FACILITY CLOSURES BY FIRM SIZE CATEGORY:"
REGULATORY ALTERNATIVE 26
Firm size based on
employment (1989)
Small (<750)
Large (>750)
Total, all firmsb
Operating facilities
Baseline With regulation
211 205
354 349
565 554
Facility closures
6
5
11
'Facility closures result from the market impact model.
bExcludes one mill in the facility-level analysis since owned by company excluded from firm-level
analysis due to lack of necessary data.
6-30
-------
6.22.2 Employment Loss
The distribution of employment changes across small and large firms is presented in
Table 6-24. Firm-level employment changes are calculated as the sum of net employment
changes at facilities owned by the firm. The facility-level employment changes associated with
the regulations are estimates from the market impact model.
63,2.3 Profitability Impacts
Several ratios are commonly used to measure company profitability, including return on
assets, return on equity, and return on sales. For all these measures, higher values are
unambiguously preferred over lower values. In Tables 6-25 through 6-27, we compare the
profitability measures computed for potentially affected firms to the benchmark ratios reported
in Section 3.5.4.2, Tables 3-32 through 3-34. The tables indicate that the changes due to
regulation vary across both firm size and profitability measure. In the case of the return to sales,
the percentage of firms below the upper quartile increases for both size categories, the
percentage below the median increases for large firms and declines for small firms, and the
percentage below the lower quartile benchmark declines for both small and large firms. This
result reflects a general decline in profitability (as measured by the return on sales) across all
large firms above the median benchmark and small firms above the upper quartile benchmark,
while also indicating a general increase across all firms below the median benchmark.
Alternatively, in the cases of the return on assets and the return on equity, the percentage
of firms below the benchmark levels increases and decreases across small and large firms. For
the return on assets, the percentage of small firms below each benchmark level declines, while it
increases in each case for large firms. This indicates an overall increase in profitability, as
measured by the return on assets, for small firms and an overall decline in the profitability for
large firms due to imposition of the regulations. For the return on equity, the percentage of
small firms below each benchmark level also declines, but the percentage of large firms below the
upper quartile and median benchmarks increases and below the lower quartile level it decreases.
This indicates an overall increase in profitability, as measured by the return on equity, for small
6-31
-------
TABLE 6-24
CHANGE IN EMPLOYMENT BY FIRM SIZE CATEGORY:*
REGULATORY ALTERNATIVE 26
Firm size based on
employment (1989)
Small (<750)
Large (>750)
Total, all firms
Total employment
Baseline With regulation
28,989 28,624
623,455 622,706
652,444 651,330
Change in
employment
-365
-1,537
-1,902
'Firm-level employment changes are the sum of employment changes at facilities owned by the
firm. The facility-level employment changes result from the market impact model.
6-32
-------
S
1
Z
Cfl
O
l-H ^
2 O
g|ve
M ^ ^
S3 SH ^^
05 C
BELOW INDUSTRY
[TH REGULATION:
ILATORY ALTERNA1
(/> S >->
5 !> O
*^ ^r fifi
fa 5
55 td
^j ^^
§§
£ i
U
U
as
Cu
I
13
ss
W)
s
CN
(S
X
IS
i
ca
a
e
5 •§ /~^
^a
< £
cu
_a
1^
a
5 "J ^
^t s *^^
ol)
_O
a
e
s - ~
^ a^
£
w
P
OB
BQ
8> a
a^
8 -
C en
S <"
0. ±
CT\ 0s! \O
r-^ T-H oc3
t^ «O p
r~- «ri m
W) 4> «J
o .-= =
•s t: c
"" 3 S
« t> rt S
| & 1 |
c D 2 J
-------
3
3
s
CO
Is
«<5 Cz)
"co
S O
§ Z
U 65 «s
MS BELOW INDUSTRY BEN
WITH REGULATION: RETl
!GULATORY ALTERNATIVE
o! o H
El
ts< "^*
o w
w £
o -a
< «
H ^
w «
(J
CJ
0,
. »
ts
^
en
1
IS
I
tfl
i
c
_
"3
S
CO
a
0
J3 S ^^
^ ^^
1^
I
S §,
85
ca
a
as 5 >^
J2 H ^
Jff
1*
a
^o
•J _85 J^
1^ ^^ C**
J_
S 2S
C3
ea
..
c^a
H|
A) W3
£ —
oq rs o\
cs i-5 cs
^^ ^O CO
CO ON (S
cs «o \d
t^ >O CO
C^ ^D ^^\
OO O CO
CO CO O
VO TJ- CO
p t~; CO
r- m co
c/a O 4>
.2 -p -"5
g « «
^3 3
i5 °" c CT
rt jr? rt ^-
III!
-------
TABLE 6-27
hH
ce
°^
SE
2 o*
a w
5 z
2°
sis
z ^
w C ^
MS BELOW INDUSTRY B
WITH REGULATION: RE
:GULATORY ALTERNATE
05 -» W
B§«
Cb ^^
O w
w S
03
^ w
C M
^r^ ^^
u sa
u
&
u
OH
i
1
a
o
3 "-5 ^^
.t! _w kS>
t^ »3 «y*
F
V
1^
S« ^— ,
pa
i
ts
a
s
(S
_
"S
en
a
e
J3 *5
••• >S ^6
£ SD~
a
Ig
e
JS ~3 ^
S -a #
* S*'"""'
u
= —
v ^R
BO s^x
«
v
Sc
II
O t£A
V <*rf
C CA
£ J
VO T-H 0
ON »O O
V^ ^^ CO
CO O l>
S T ro
oo oo r-i
t"» O C5
^D C^ CO
Tj- T-H CO
C^* ^" CO
O t~; O
ts r4 o
V} ^f CO
CD CD ro
o oci »o
\O •* CO
CO 1) t>
O ?"-* •"*
'5 e '£
2 « «
""3 3
^ o- cr
U« *->
c^ ** rt ^*
E ex '"S >
J= CX « o
0 — 5 ^ S
c -1 *s 1-1
m
6-35
-------
firms and a general decline in profitability for large firms at the higher tail of the distribution
along with a general increase for large firms at the lower tail of the distribution.
The previous observations are supported by the summary statistics for the measures of
profitability shown in Table 6-28. The summary statistics include the mean, minimum, and
maximum values for each measure in baseline and with regulation across small, large, and all
firms in the industry. A comparison of the values in baseline and after imposition of the
regulations provides more detail on the distributional changes in these profitability measures
across firms.
As Table 6-28 illustrates, the mean return on sales slightly declines for all firms after
imposition of the regulation. This finding is also true for small firms, while the mean return on
sales for large firms increases by an inconsiderable amount. Further, the mean return on assets
increase for all firms with regulation, fueled by the increase in the mean return for small firms
from 8.8 to 9.4 percent. Alternatively, the mean return on assets for large firms slightly declines
from 5.57 to 5.40 percent. As measured across all firms, the post-regulation mean return on
equity increases from the baseline level of 20.4 to 22.3 percent. As a group, small firms realize
an increase in the mean return on equity, while the mean return on equity for large firms very
slightly decreases. Overall, a disproportionate impact on small firms is not evident from the
profitability analysis.
6.22.4 Bankruptcy Analysis
Table 6-29 provides the with-regulation bankruptcy prediction by firm size. This can be
compared to the baseline prediction shown in Table 3-38. Under regulation, the likelihood of
financial failure for small firms is not affected. However, the likelihood of financial failure for
large firms declines because one large firm moved into the indeterminate range after regulation.
The number of firms in the indeterminate range increases by nine firms. Two-thirds of these
firms are small, six out of nine. As seen in Table 6-29, regulation reduces the number of firms
for which bankruptcy was unlikely in baseline by 7.3 percent, or eight firms. Nearly two-thirds of
these firms are small, five out of eight. Small firms, as a group, incur a 20 percent reduction in
6-36
-------
TABLE 6-28
SUMMARY STATISTICS FOR KEY MEASURES OF
PROFITABILITY IN BASELINE AND WITH REGULATION
BY FIRM SIZE CATEGORY:
REGULATORY ALTERNATIVE 26
Measure of
Profitability/
Summary Statistics
Return on sales
Mean
Minimum
Maximum
Return on assets
Mean
Minimum
Maximum
Return on equity
Mean
Minimum
Maximum
Baseline
Small
firms
5.39
-21.55
28.51
8.80
-47.07
62.35
25.58
-179.83
664.00
Large
firms All firms
5.23 5.34
-77.92
17.36
5.57 7.84
-149.27
24.55
8.40 20.40
-262.42
88.91
With
Small
firms
5.34
-46.53
28.98
9.37
-45.56
60.60
28.31
-185.71
662.91
regulation
Large
firms All
5.21
-68.32
17.36
5.40
-140.37
26.15
8.27
-246.77
94.77
firms
5.30
8.20
22.30
6-37
-------
TABLE 6-29
WITH-REGULATION BANKRUPTCY PREDICTION
BY FIRM SIZE:
REGULATORY ALTERNATIVE 26
All Companies
Bankruptcy
Likely
Firm Size Based on Employment
(1989)
Z'-Score
Prediction*
Small
(<750)
Percent
Change
Large
(>750)
Percent
Change
Percent
Total Change
0.0
-16.7
14
-6.7
Indeterminant
Bankruptcy
Unlikely
59
82
5.4
-3.5
38
20
18.8
-20.0
97
102
10.2
-7.3
•Bankruptcy prediction is based on Altman's Z'-score for manufacturing companies. If a
company's Z'-score is < 1.23, the model predicts that bankruptcy is likely. If a company's Z'-
score is > 2.90, the model predicts that bankruptcy is unlikely. Z'-scores between 1.23 and 2.90
fall in the indeterminant range, and the model makes no prediction for these companies.
6-38
-------
the number unlikely to become bankrupt, while the large category shows only a 3.5 percent
decline after imposition of the regulation.
63 SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
The financial and market model analyses use different methods to examine the impacts
on small entities. The financial model compares the number of closures and the losses in jobs,
shipments (tonnage and value), and exports and changes in financial ratios. The market model
also examines the number of closures and job losses, and includes an analysis of profitability and
bankruptcy impacts.
Both approaches provide consistent results. Using the number of employees at a
company to define size (as used by the Small Business Administration), small entities are not
more severely affected than large entities. Very small companies show the least amount of
impacts and, as indicated by the market model analysis, large companies generally are more
severely affected than small ones. Using the number of employees at a facility to define size
provides a more conservative analysis. In the financial model, only one very small facility that is
also a very small company is adversely affected by the regulatory alternatives. There is one
parameter (exports) where small facilities show greater proportional impacts but there are several
parameters where large facilities show greater proportional impacts (closures, shipments, and
employment).
In general, there is no consistent pattern of disproportionate impacts on small entities.
The results indicate the regulatory alternatives do not cause a significant impact on a substantial
number of small entities. This conclusion is reached for all definitions of small entity used in
both analytical models.
6-39
-------
-------
APPENDIX A;
MARKET IMPACT METHODOLOGY AND MODEL
A.1 INTRODUCTION AND OVERVIEW OF APPROACH
The U.S. Environmental Protection Agency's (EPA's) Office of Air and Radiation
(OAR) and Office of Water (OW) are developing regulations to control the release of air and
water pollutants that result from manufacturing pulp and paper. The OAR contributes to the
regulatory development effort by providing analyses and supporting documents that describe the
likely economic and financial effects of the proposed guidelines on the regulated community and
other entities of interest.
Generally, when evaluating the economic impact of regulations, the EPA may consider
estimates of the impact on the following types of variables for the economic impact analysis:
• Facility-level impacts:
— costs (capital and annual operating)
— closures *
— employment
— production
• Market-level impacts for selected products:
— product price changes
— production changes
— consumption changes
— changes in imports
— changes in exports
Further, the Agency must also consider the requirements of E.O. 12291. That Order
requires a Regulatory Impact Analysis (RIA), which is essentially a benefit-cost analysis, of all
"major" regulations. The Order defines "major" as any regulation having annual costs of over
$100 million, causing significant changes in costs or prices, or resulting in significant market
A-l
-------
disruptions. Also, under the Regulatory Flexibility Act the Agency must provide a Regulatory
Flexibility Analysis (RFA) of the effects on small entities if a "substantial" number of these
entities are significantly affected. If an RFA is prepared, the Agency must also make a special
effort to design the regulation to address the effects of the regulation on small entities.
The total number of mills directly and indirectly affected by these regulations depends on
the policy options considered, but the number will be some subset of the U.S. mills included in
the EPA's 1990 National Census of Pulp, Paper, and Paperboard Manufacturing Facilities.1
The key challenge facing the designer of the analytical approach for addressing the
economic impact of regulations on the pulp and paper industry is how to integrate facility-level
impacts with the market(s) for their outputs in a realistic and conceptually correct manner. This
task is complicated by the complex production relationships and the degree of product
differentiation that characterize the pulp and paper manufacturing industry. Despite these
complexities, we developed an economic model that assesses product market responses for 37
markets and facility-level impacts on 338 directly and 228 indirectly affected mills within the U.S.
pulp and paper industry.
The model is a multidimensional Lotus spreadsheet incorporating various data sources to
provide an empirical characterization of the U.S. pulp and paper industry and product markets
for a base year of 1989. This base year of analysis was chosen because it is the last year for
which facility-specific production and technical data were available from the 1990 National
Census and for which supporting economic data were readily available. The model analyzes
market adjustments for 31 paper and paperboard product markets and 6 market pulps.
Integrated facilities and paper-making facilities constitute those facilities supplying final paper
and paperboard products, while the pulp mills and those integrated mills involved in the market
for pulp, cither as a supplier or dcmandcr, constitute those facilities included in the model for
market pulps. The model also includes a foreign trade sector with imports and exports for each
paper and paperboard product and market pulp.
The exogenous shock to the economic model is the imposition of the regulations and the
corresponding control costs (i.e., the installed capital and per-unit output operating and
A-2
-------
maintenance [O&M] exists of the regulatory alternative). We annualized the installed capital
costs of the controls for each facility using firm-specific costs of capital from the 1990 National
Census of Pulp, Paper, and Paperboard Manufacturing Facilities. The annualized installed capital
costs enter the model at the facility-level, while the per-unit output O&M costs enter at the
product-level for all facilities affected by the regulatory alternative.
We obtained model parameters and supporting data from the EPA's 1990 National
Census of Pulp, Paper, and Paperboard Manufacturing Facilities, industry data sources, and
econometric estimation. Specification and parameterization of facility-specific, upward-sloping
supply curves for each product allow the model to take facility-specific reactions to the regulatory
costs (shifts in facility-level supply curves aggregated to the market level) and determine new
equilibria in all product markets. Facilities may cease to produce a particular product by closing
a product line, which is determined by the shutdown point on the supply curve, or they may stop
production altogether by closing the entire facility, which is determined by comparing total
revenues and total costs (including regulatory control costs) at the facility level.
We incorporated a competitive market structure to compute the equilibrium prices and
quantities of all commodities in the system. Demand for the "final" commodities in the system-
that is, commodities whose demand is exogenous-is expressed in equation form. Domestic .
demand elasticities are econometrically estimated for all paper and paperboard products.
Domestic demand for market pulp is derived from paper and paperboard production decisions
via fixed input coefficients or purchased input ratios, which determine the amount of market
pulp needed to produce paper or paperboard at each facility. Similarly, import supply and
export demand are expressed in equation form with derived estimates of import supply and
export demand elasticities. The model analyzes market adjustments for 31 paper and paperboard
product markets and for 6 market pulps by employing a process of tatonnement whereby prices
approach equilibrium through successive correction via a Walrasian auctioneer. To our
knowledge this empirical model is the only one that integrates the facility and market in a
conceptually correct manner that addresses multiple products and derived demand relationships.
The major outputs of this model arc market-level adjustments in price and quantity for
all affected products as well as facility-level adjustments in production, including product-line or
A-3
-------
facility closures. We estimated impacts on foreign trade through comparing baseline and with-
regulation levels of exports and imports of affected products. We used the market adjustments
in price and quantity to calculate the changes in the aggregate economic welfare using applied
welfare economics principles. The net change in economic welfare associated with the regulation
is measured by consumer and producer surplus changes.
In addition, we also computed the changes in employment attributable to the change in
output from mills. The change in output results from both changes in production at the affected
facilities and facility and product-line closures. We computed worker dislocation costs given the
industry employment losses based on the method outlined in Anderson and Chandran.2
A.2 FEATURES OF THE PULP AND PAPER INDUSTRY
For this analysis, a paper or paperboard product is formed by two processes: pulping-
bleaching and papermaking. As seen in Figure A-l, pulpwood is the raw material input into the
pulping process, which results in pulp that may or may not be bleached depending on its final
end use. Chemical pulping and bleaching processes and secondary wastewater treatment are the
three major processes the regulations will affect. Air and water pollutants resulting specifically
from wood preparation or papermaking processes are not addressed by the regulations or this
analysis; however, this analysis is capable of including these activities.
A.2.1 Pulp Production Processes
Pulp can be manufactured by a variety of processes that separate the wood into its cell
components. Important pulping processes are
• Chemical
» Semichemical
• Mechanical
A-4
-------
Pulpwood
Pulping Process
Unbleached
Pulp
Secondary Fibers
i
Bleaching Process
Bleached
Pulp
Bleached
Secondary
Fiber
Unbleached
Secondary
Fiber
Papermaking Process
Paper Product
Figure A-l Paper production process
A-5
-------
• Thermomechanical, chemimechanical, and cheraithermomechanical
» Bleaching and brightening
Each process imbues the final product with special characteristics according to the relative
balance of the components remaining in the pulp. The characteristics affect the quality of the
pulp, thus dictating its end use and, in turn, influence the quality of the paper or board
produced. In addition, pulps may or may not undergo a further bleaching or brightening process
after manufacturing.
A3..1.1 Chemical Pulping Method
Chemical pulping methods involve a chemical reaction between the lignin and the active
chemicals in the pulping liquor. Kraft (or sulfate) and sulfite are two chemical processes that use
different chemicals and produce pulps with slightly different characteristics. Kraft pulping first
cooks the chips in a mixture of sodium hydroxide and sodium sulfide (white liquor); the
procedure is halted before the pulp is completely delignified. The mixture is then separated into
vapor, liquid, and pulp. Next the pulp is washed and may be bleached. Finally, chemical and by-
product recovery is employed to convert used chemicals, tall oil, and turpentine into reusable
inputs or products. Both hardwoods and softwoods can be used in the kraft process, and it
produces a very strong pulp that can be combined with weaker pulps.
The sulfite pulping process is similar to the kraft process in that both processes use
sulfur-based chemicals to remove lignin from the wood. The difference between sulfite and kraft
pulping is that the. alkaline white liquor is replaced with an acidic liquor made of sulfurous acid
and the bisulfate ion. Fiber furnishes used in this process include softwoods such as spruce, fir,
and hemlock. The primary advantage of the sulfite method is that it produces a pulp with a
lower residual lignin content. As a result, sulfite pulp is easier to bleach and requires fewer
bleaching steps, making it better suited for papermaking applications. However, the lower
residual lignin content causes sulfite pulp to be weaker than kraft pulp because the chemical
recovery stage of the sulfite process is less thorough than that of the kraft process.
A-6
-------
The economic feasibility of chemical recovery is ultimately determined by the cost of the
initial compounds. Calcium (limestone)-based reactions do not generally involve recovery phases
because the cost of recovery exceeds the cost of purchasing new calcium. On the other hand,
magnesium-based reactions are followed by recovery because magnesium recovery is less costly
than acquiring fresh magnesium.
A.2.1.2 Semichemical Method
Semichemical pulping combines aspects of chemical and mechanical treatment to pulp
hardwoods. Chips are first softened and partially delignified by using chemicals and steam and
then pulped by mechanical action. The primary method of Semichemical pulping is the neutral
sulfite method. In this method, wood chips are cooked in a neutral solution of sodium sulfite
and either sodium carbonate or sodium hydroxide. The extent of chemical delignification is
determined by the length of cooking and chemical concentration. After partial chemical
delignification, the furnish is then subjected to further nonpressurized mechanical delignification.
A.2.1.3 Meqhanical Methods
Mechanical pulping involves either shredding unchipped pulpwood with a grindstone or
fiberizing wood chips with a specially designed refiner. Mechanical pulping is used primarily for
softwoods, although variations of the mechanical process have been devised to allow mechanical
pulping of hardwoods. The mechanical pulping process simply rips loose the bond that lignin
creates, but the lignin remains attached to the cellulosic fibers. As a result, mechanical pulp is
highly opaque, making it suitable for uses such as newsprint. However, mechanical pulp
produces low strength paper that yellows easily, and the process is highly energy intensive. Two
variations of mechanical pulping are commonly used: stone groundwood and refiner
groundwood.
The stone groundwood process mechanically grinds bolts of lumber (uniformly sized,
debarked logs) against a grinding stone to separate fiber from lignin. The stone is then cleaned
A-7
-------
with water to recover the pulp, the resulting slurry is screened to remove oversized pieces, and
finally water is removed. The stone groundwood method produces short strands of pulp, which
accounts for the pulp's weakness. Refiner processing replaces the grinding stone with a pair of
discs and is designed to generate longer, stronger strands of pulp fiber. Grooved discs spinning
against each other in opposite directions effectively shred the pulp instead of grinding it. The
main disadvantage of refiner pulping is that it produces a darker pulp that is more difficult to
bleach than stone groundwood pulp.
A2.I.4 Thermomechaniccd, Chemimechanical, and Chemi-thermomechanical Pulping
Processes
Thermomechanical pulping is a fourth pulping process. In this method, steam is used to
soften the fibers before shredding. The chips are presteamed or refined in one or more stages of
pressurized refining or followed by atmospheric refining. Following the brief cooking process,
the pulp is mechanically defibrated in refiners. Thermomechanical pulping, which produces pulp
of low strength but higher than the groundwood and refiner mechanical processes, is used for
products such as newsprint, publication papers, and fiberboard.
Another pulping process is chemimechanical pulping, which produces a pulp of slightly
higher strength than thermomechanical pulping. The method allows hardwoods to be pulped
mechanically by first subjecting the wood to a chemical softening stage. Two major processes are
used: the chemigroundwood process and the cold soda process. Chemigroundwood processing
cooks bolts of timber in an alkaline sulfite solution prior to mechanical grinding. The sulfite
solution softens the fiber to make it more responsive to the grinding stone. Cold soda
chemimechanical processing uses a caustic soda to soften wood chips at room temperature. The
chips are then pulped by the mechanical refiner method. Chemimechanical pulping is similar to
scmichemical pulping, but the semichcmical pulping process employs a chemical stage to partially
dclignify the furnish, whereas the chemimechanical method relies exclusively on mechanical
dclignification. Chemical treatment in the chemimechanical process is only a means of preparing
the furnish for mechanical delignification; the semichemical process supplements mechanical
dclignification with chemical dclignification.
A-8
-------
Chemi-thermomechanical pulping employs chemicals and heat to break down the chips,
followed by mechanical defibration. The wood is cooked in a chemical liquor of sodium sulfite
and sodium carbonates at elevated temperatures to prepare it for defibration. Some paper
products produced from this type of pulp are newsprint, tissue, and board.
A2.1J5 Bleaching and Brightening
Bleaching may be an additional process added to any of the pulping methods described
above. Bleaching is a means of whitening pulp and involves further delignification as well as
alteration of chromophoric compounds present in the pulp fiber. Bleaching permanently alters
the pulp by removing lignin. Thus, in addition to whitening the pulp, bleaching increases the
longevity of whiteness and retards discoloring in the final product. The main disadvantage
associated with bleaching is that lignin removal weakens the pulp. The bleaching process can be
either single stage or multi-stage, depending on the desired color of the final product. The
following five procedures are generally used in bleaching: chlorine, chlorine dioxide,
hypochlorite, peroxide, and ozone. The order in which the steps occur varies and is determined
by the degree of delignification required, the wood type, and the pulping process used.
As Figure A-l shows, secondary fibers may also be used as inputs to the bleaching
process and papermaking process. Secondary fibers are any type of fiber obtained from
wastepapers and other used, reclaimable fiber sources.
Brightening, the alternative and the complement to bleaching, involves altering only the
chromophoric compounds present in the pulp. No delignification occurs. As a result, the
brightening process is less damaging to the strength of the pulp, but the whiteness of the pulp
lasts only temporarily, and exposure to the sun yellows brightened pulps easily.
A-9
-------
A.2.2 Paper Production Processes
The papermaking process uses pulp as an input to produce paper and paperboard
products. The process begins with refining, which mechanically cuts and macerates pulp to
convert raw fiber into a form suitable for papermaking. Pulps also may be mixed with other pulp
types to enhance strength or other characteristics. Additives to impart certain characteristics may
be added, and then the stock, or furnish, is pumped to the paper machine.
Three basic steps occur in paper and paperboard production:
1. A web of fiber is formed from a fiber and water suspension on a paper machine
wire.
2. Water is pressed out of the web.
3. The remaining water is driven off by heat.
A variety of machines make paper, but the two most common are the fourdrinier and cylinder
machines. The fourdrinier machine typically is used for manufacturing a variety of paper grades
and lightweight bonds and the cylinder machine for multi-ply paperboard or building board
grades.
Each paper or paperboard product may be made using some combination of bleached or
unbleached pulps and secondary fiber depending on the desired characteristics of the final
product. These combinations are very closely related-the pulpwood input (hardwood or
softwood) requires a particular pulping process that results in a certain type of pulp, which may
or may not require bleaching to obtain the brightness required for the final product. For
example, the "recipe" for uncoated free sheet might call for 80 percent kraft pulp (from the kraft
pulping process) and 20 percent groundwood pulp (from the mechanical pulping process) with
each type of pulp bleached with a particular bleaching sequence.
A-10
-------
A.2.3 Producers
The pulp and paper industry is characterized by both nonintegrated and vertically
integrated mills. Vertically integrated mills rely mostly on their own production of pulp to
produce paper and paperboard products, while nonintegrated mills include pulp mills that
produce market pulp as well as paper mills that purchase market pulp to produce paper and
paperboard products. Mills producing low-value products are usually integrated, and mills
making specialized, high-value products are usually nonintegrated. Those vertically integrated
mills without enough internally produced pulp are also demanders of market pulp; those mills
that produce an excess supply of pulp are suppliers of market pulp.
A mill is defined as a single physical entity with a unique geographic location that
includes one or several production lines. A mill may have several parallel decision-making units
in place at once, reflecting the decision-maker's choice to produce multiple outputs. For this
study, three types of mills exist for producing pulp and paper: pulp mills, paper mills, and
integrated facilities. Their total number and distinguishing characteristics are as follows:
Pulp mills (28)—mills engaging solely in the production of pulp to be sold on the
pulp market for use as an input in the production process of a paper or
paperboard product. Pulp mills include mills producing pulp from both virgin
fiber as well as secondary fibers such as recycled paper, rags, linters (cottonseed
fiber fuzz), and straw.
Paper mills (303)—mills producing paper and paperboard products from market-
purchased pulp produced from pulp mills and integrated mills. Paper mills
include makers of all paper and paperboard products in the National Census that
do not produce their own pulp on-site but may repulp secondary fiber as an input
to production.
Integrated mills (235)—mills producing not only final products but also the pulp
required to manufacture these products. Also included are mills that have some
production lines devoted to paper production and others devoted to market pulp
production (a mill that is both a pulp mill and a paper mill but that does not use
the pulp produced on-site as an input to the on-site paper production).3
This categorization of mills divides them only according to whether they engage in market
activities to meet their input needs; it does not discriminate according to facility size. Hence, this
A-ll
-------
definition does not imply that an integrated facility is necessarily larger than a pulp facility;
however, in reality the integrated mill may dwarf the pulp mill. This characterization refers to
each mill's evaluation of the relative costs of purchasing or manufacturing their input; integrated
mills produce their input rather than purchase it, whereas nonintegrated facilities rely on the
market to meet their input demand.
A.2.4 Products and Markets
The analysis described in the following sections accounts for all marketable commodities
involved in producing pulp and paper. The first marketable product is pulp, either bleached or
unbleached, and the second marketable product is the final paper or paperboard product. An
additional marketable commodity is secondary fiber. All of these products are consumed and
produced domestically, as well as traded internationally. Therefore, domestic producers export
some pulp and paper products to other countries, and foreign producers supply their pulp and
paper products to U.S. markets. This section includes tables and figures on value, quantity, and
price trends over the past decade for aggregate products (i.e., market pulp, paper, and
paperboard).
Domestic quantity and value shipped for pulp products from 1981 to 1989 are shown in
Table A-l (see Figures A-2 and A-3). In 1989, the domestic shipments of pulp products were
valued at $7.4 billion, which was an increase of 115 percent over the pulp shipment value in
1981. As shown in Table A-l and Figure A-2, the quantity of pulp shipped grew fairly steadily
over the 9-year period, reaching 11.4 million tons in 1989. The average price for pulp per ton
was approximately $645 (see Table A-l). Aggregate prices per ton for pulp, paper, and
paperboard products are shown in Figure A-4. Special Alpha and dissolving woodpulp products
had the highest estimated price per ton at $735.33. Bleached sulfate pulps were close to average
for all pulps with a price of $646 per ton. Lower end pulps included unbleached sulfate, $384
per ton, and unbleached secondary fiber, $417 per ton.
Table A-2 shows domestic quantity and value shipped for paper products from 1981 to
1989 (see also Figures A-2 and A-3). Total paper products in 1989 were valued at $33.3 billion;
A-l 2
-------
TABLE A-l
U.S. PRODUCTION OF PULP: 1981-19394's' 6'7> 8
Year
Quantity Shipped Short
Tons
Value Shipped (S103)
Price/Ton
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
8,259,272
8,581,831
9,359,292
9,927,473
9,952,129
11,132,855
11,575,838
11,553,220
11,423,483
3,424,840
3,238,794
3,252,707
4,001,373
3,686,080
4,017,736
5,135,618
6,494,338
7,369,559
414.67
377.40
347.54
403.06
370.38
360.89
443.65
562.12
645.12
A-13
-------
40,000,000 -•
35,000,000 --
30,000,000
25,000,000 •-
20,000,000 -
15,000,000 • •
10,000,000 j
5,000,000 "
o-
• • •-
l • •
| 1 1 1 i i
1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986
Year
• Market Pulp D Paper products
I 1 1
1987 1988 1989
A ,
" Haperboard Products
Figure A-2 U.S. quantities shipped of pulp, paper, and paperboard products: 1981-1989
A-14
-------
35,000,000 -r
30,000,000 ••
25,000,000 --
o 20,000,000
r~
-------
1
900.00 j
800.00 --
700.00 +
600.00
500.00
400.00
300.00
200.00 --
100.00 -•
0.00
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
Year
1986
1987
1988
1989
' Market Pulp
Paper Products
' Paperboard Products
Figure A-4. Price per ton for U.S. pulp, paper, and paperboard products: 1981-1989
A-16
-------
TABLE A-2
U.S. PRODUCTION OF PAPER PRODUCTS:
1981-19899'10'11'12'13
Year
Total Paper
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
Printing and
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
Quantity Shipped Short
Tons
Products
29,815,913
30,150,893
32,205,274
32,989,205
32,317,371
34,859,400
36,133,517
38,005,856
38,073,553
Writing Paper
20,790,643
20,986,247
22,662,033
23,924,514
23,514,596
25,448,416
26,799,576
27,948,521
27,878,961
Value Shipped
(S103)
19,607,188
20,157,769
21,399,481
24,271,824
23,550,366
25,782,800
26,835,126
31,719,331
33,302,931
13,339,811
13,553,318
14,504,942
17,135,025
16,661,865
17,671,871
19,090,537
22,833,368
23,334,857
Price/Ton
657.61
668.56
664.47
728.72
739.62
739.62
742.67
834.59
874.70
641.63
645.82
640.05
708.58
694.42
694.42
712.34
816.98
837.01
Packaging and Industrial Converting Paper
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
. 1986
1987
1988
1989
4,994,353
4,873,388
5,096,948
4,975,517
4,686,169
4,642,574
4,437,607
4,874,730
4.743,575
2,717,212
2,766,858
2,917,972
3,118,102
2,836,997
2.898,312
3,173,890
3,746,612
3,910,349
544.06
567.75
572.49
605.40
624.29
624.29
715.23
768.58
824.35
A-17
-------
printing and writing paper products were valued at $23.3 billion, and packaging and industrial
converting paper products were valued at $3.9 billion. In 1989, value of shipments increased
almost 70 percent over 1981. The largest increase in growth was in the printing and writing
papers sector, which increased almost 75 percent in 1989 over 1981. Shipments of paper
products in 1989 totaled 38.1 million tons. The average prices of paper products per ton from
1981 to 1989 are compared with average prices for pulp and paperboard products in Figure A-4.
The average estimated price per ton for paper products was $875 (Table A-2). Printing and
writing and packaging and industrial paper products had lower average values per ton: $837 and
$824, respectively. The two market segments had a lower average price per ton than the total
paper market throughout the 9-year period. Individual products with a higher price per ton than
the average included cotton fiber writing paper, $2,040; special industrial paper, $1,718; and
glassine, greaseproof, and vegetable parchment, $1,359. The lowest priced paper product was
newsprint at $490 per ton. Other paper products valued less than $700 per ton included
unbleached kraft packaging paper, shipping sack, and uncoated groundwood paper.
Table A-3 shows quantity and value shipped for paperboard products from 1981 to 1989
(sec Figures A-2 and A-3). Total shipments of paperboard were almost $16.3 billion, which
represents an increase of 63 percent over the 1981 value. As Figure A-2 and Table A-3
illustrate, quantities shipped of paperboard dipped in 1982 and 1985 slightly but otherwise rose
steadily over the 1981 to 1989 period, reaching 38 million tons in 1989. Paperboard products
had a price per ton less than that of paper products in 1989 at an average of $427 per ton (Table
A-3 and Figure A-4). The lower value per ton for paperboard products is illustrated by the fact
that in 1989 paperboard products accounted for approximately half (38 million tons) of all paper
and paperboard products shipped but accounted for only 33 percent of the value shipped. All of
the bleached packaging and industrial paperboard products had a higher than average price per
ton. The highest average prices per ton for individual products were molded pulp products,
51,196; folding carton boxboard, $721; and milk carton board, $719. Hardboard and insulating
board had the lowest price per ton with $337 and $338, respectively.
A-18
-------
TABLE A-3
U.S. PRODUCTION OF PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS:
1981-198914-1S> 16> "•18
Year
Quantity Shipped Short
Tons
Value Shipped
(Sio3)
Price/Ton
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
30,566,254
28,912,522
31,470,079
33,514,510
33,030,693
35,613,237
36,989,614
37,762,521
38,047,313
9,993,099
9,138,993
9,738,689
11,572,125
10,562,943
11,452,177
13,531,922
15,235,749
16,256,939
326.93
316.09
309.46
345.29
319.79
321.57
365.83
403.46
427.28
A-19
-------
A.2.5 Foreign Trade
In 1989, the United States was a net importer of total pulp, paper, and paperboard
products. Imports in 1989 totaled $10.2 billion. The majority of U.S. pulp imports come from
Canada and secondly Latin America. The top three countries exporting paper and paperboard
products to the U.S. are Canada, Finland, and Sweden. In 1989 the U.S. exported approximately
$6.6 billion in pulp, paper, and paperboard products. The two largest importing countries of
U.S. pulp products are Japan and Germany. Major importers of U.S. paper and paperboard
products are Canada, Japan, and the U.K.1'
As shown in Table A-4 and Figure A-5, the U.S. was a net exporter of pulp products in
1989 and had been since 1986. In 1989, exports totaled $3.6 billion, approximately 48 percent of
the domestic value of shipments. Imports were 41 percent of the domestic value of shipments
and totaled almost $3.0 billion. Total quantities of pulp exported and imported were about 6.4
and 5 million tons, respectively. Bleached and semi-bleached sulphate and soda woodpulp were
the pulp products imported and exported in the greatest amount.20
The U.S. was a net importer of paper products in 1989, as it was for the eight years prior
to 1989 (see Table A-5 and Figure A-6). Exports represent 3.6 percent of the domestic value of
shipments whereas imports represent 20.7 percent. Imports to the U.S. were mainly from the
printing and writing paper segment; newsprint was the number one imported paper product.
Imports of printing and writing paper were over 27 percent of the domestic value of printing and
writing paper shipped. In 1989, major imports in the printing and writing group were newsprint
and uncoated groundwood paper. Exports were led in this segment by newsprint and clay coated
printing papers. In the packaging and industrial segment, imports were led by the glassine,
greaseproof, and vegetable parchment product group. Shipping sack was the product exported in
the largest quantity.25
Exports and imports of papcrboard products for 1981 to 1989 are shown in Table A-6
and Figure A-7. As with pulp, the U.S. is a net exporter of these products, exporting $1.7 billion,
or about 10 percent of the value of pulp shipments in 1989. Imports were $3.3 million, or less
than 2 percent of the value of total pulp shipments. However, by 1989 imports increased by a
A-20
-------
TABLE A-4
FOREIGN TRADE OF MARKET PULP: 1981-198$"'22
Year
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
Export
Quantity
Short Tons
3,809,545
3,499,208
3,746,826
3,678,468
3,902,326
4,615,769
5,071,332
5,729,859
6,353,213
Export
Value
C$103)
1,746,506
1,486,885
1,431,827
1,565,493
1,425,560
2,073,541
2,350,742
3,026,445
3,613,114
Export
Price/Ton
458.46
424.92
382.14
425.58
365.31
449.23
463.54
528.19
568.71
Import
Quantity
Short Tons
4,086,698
3,655,786
4,093,436
4,490,081
4,465,746
4,581,760
4,850,238
5,038,158
5,004,366
Import
Value
(S103)
1,764,287
1,493,241
1,472,478
1,844,766
1,520,907
1,601,378
2,069,394
2,663,424
2,980,197
Import
Price/
Tons
431.71
408.46
359.72
410.85
340.57
349.51
426.66
528.65
595.52
A-21
-------
4,000,000 --
3,500,000 •-
3,000,000 ••
2,500,000 -•
1981
p
£
o
Q
2,000,000 -
L
1,500,000 -
1,000,000 -
500,000 -
n -
Jl^ ^X"^ ^^^
r~"^--^n ^^^-:* r^^—-^^^
1 1 ! 1 1 1 1 1
1982
1983
1984
1985
Year
1986
1987
1988
1989
Exports
Imports
Figure A-5 U.S. foreign trade of market pulp: 1981-1989
A-22
-------
TABLE A-5
FOREIGN TRADE OF PAPER PRODUCTS: 1981-198923'24
Export Export
Quantity Value
Year Short Tons (SIO3)
Export
Price/
Ton
Import
Quantity
Short Tons
Import
Value
C$103)
Import
Price/
Tons
Total Paper Products
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1,008,409
840,445
773,760
810,933
779,000
883,768
921,419
1,102,489.
1,465,752
Printing and Writing
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
Packaging
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
653,777
554,274
496,690
509,723
517,211
582,909
588,865
714,503
1,102,998
846,775
679,069
599,557
632,493
594,337
642,728
776,226
988,031
1,233,526
Paper
494,310
325,423
325,423
353,889
333,223
379,825
452,732
608,521
822,549
and Industrial Converting
354,632
286,171
277,370
301,210
261,789
352,464
296,971
274,134
278,604
261.114
839.71
807.99
774.86
779.96
762.95
727.26
842.42
896.18
841.57
756.08
587.12
655.18
694.28
644.27
651.60
768.82
851.67
745.74
Paper
993.89
1,037.74
988.33
924.95
997.42
7,716,284
7,381,252
8,189,498
10,113,718
10,637,427
10,925,453
11,765,207
12,063,790
11,814,260
7,615,656
7,294,771
8,070,359
9,937,922
10,409,435
10,616,810
11,396,765
11,661,032
11,286,377
100,628
86,481
119,138
175,796
227,992
3,247,846
3,226,307
3,428,868
4,592,641
4,906,913
5,051,916
5,768,703
6,799,044
6,900,798
3,171,894
3,157,203
3,344,950
4,469,714
4,754,971
4,862,153
5,533,785
6,518,760
6,375,753
75,954
69,104
83,919
122,927
151,942
420.91
437.09
418.69
454.10
461.29
462.40
490.32
563.59
584.11
416.50
432.80
414.47
449.76
456.79
457.97
485.56
559.02
564.91
754.80
799.07
704.38
699.26
666.44
A-23
-------
TABLE A-5 (cont.)
Year
1986
1987
1988
1989
Export
Quantify
Short Tons
300,859
332,554
387,986
362,754
Export
Value
(Sio3)
262,903
323,494
379,510
410,977
Export
Price/
Ton
873.84
972.76
978.15
1,132.94
Import
Quantity
Short Tons
308,643
368,442
402,758
527,883
Import
Value
C$103)
189,763
234,918
280,284
525,045
Import
Price/
Tons
614.83
637.60
695.91
994.62
A-24
-------
7,000,000 •-
6,000,000 ••
5,000,000 ••
£ 4,000,000 -•
(0
I 3,000,000
o
Q 2,000,000
1,000,000
1981 1982
-i 1 1 1 1 1 1
1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989
Year
-I
B bxports D Imports
Figure A-6 U.S. foreign trade of paper products: 1981-1989
A-25
-------
TABLE A-6
FOREIGN TRADE OF PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS:
1981-1980"-28
Year
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
Export
Quantity
Short Tons
3,025,579
2,829,968
3,210,777
3,008,283
2,801,547
3,276,516
3,657,633
3,774,075
3,793,982
Export
Value
(Sio3)
1,233,162
1,075,284
1,118,478
1,157,019
991,898
1,211,020
1,504,195
1,713,375
1,749,159
Export
Price/Ton
407.58
379.96
348.35
384.61
354.05
369.61
411.25
453.99
461.04
Import
Quantity
Short Tons
528,658
536,165
645,069
742,272
600,667
. 621,093
670,279
663,456
723,211
Import
Value
(Sio3)
114,041
117,898
153,424
189,989
167,600
195,211
226,419
238,584
330,851
Import
Price/
Tons'
215.72
219.89
237.84
255.96
279.02
314.30
337.80
359.61
457.48
A-26
-------
to
"o
0
1,800,000
1,600,000
1,400,000
1,200,000
1,000,000 "
800,000 "
600,000 -•
400,000
200,000
0
-D-
1981 1982 1983 1984 1985
Year
1986
1987
1988
1989
Exports
Imports
Figure A-7 U.S. foreign trade of paperhoard products: 19H1-1989
A-27
-------
greater percentage than exports over 1981 values. The total quantity exported in 1989 was
almost 3.8 million tons: the main products were milk carton board and linerboard. Imports
totaled 723,000 tons and were led by construction paper, unbleached kraft packaging and
paperboard, recycled paperboard, and semichemical paperboard.26
A.3 MODELING MARKET ADJUSTMENTS
Implementing regulations to control air and water pollutants from pulp and paper
•manufacturers will affect the costs of production in the U.S. pulp and paper industry. As shown
in Section 4.2 of this report, the costs of the regulations will vary across the many different mills
in the industry, depending on the production processes currently employed. Mill-level
production responses to these additional costs will determine the market impacts of the
regulations. Specifically, the cost of the regulations may induce some mills, or product lines
within mills, to close or to change their current level of production. These choices affect, and in
turn are affected by, the market price for market pulp, paper, and paperboard products.
This section examines the impact of the regulations that affect the production costs for
facilities in the U.S. pulp and paper industry. It provides an overview of the basic economic
theory of the effect the regulations may have on facility production decisions and of the
concomitant effect on pulp, paper, and paperboard prices.
An economic impact analysis should assess the market-, facility-, small business-, and
community-level impacts of proposed regulatory alternatives. A variety of approaches may be
used to quantify and evaluate economic impacts; they reflect a variety of underlying paradigms.
The neoclassical model provides the state-of-the-art paradigm for regulatory analysis and
establishes the framework for subsequent empirical modeling. The paradigm appropriate for this
industry is described below. It is based, in pan, on the industry profile information presented in
Section 2 of this report and followed by the description of an integrated approach to
implementing the conceptual model.
A-28
-------
We employed standard microeconomics concepts to model the supply of pulp, paper, and
paperboard products and the impacts of the regulations on production costs and facility output
decisions. The three main elements of the analysis are regulatory effects on the manufacturing
facility, market responses, and facility-market interactions.
A.3.1 Facility-Level Effects
At any point in time, the costs that a firm faces can be classified as either unavoidable
(sunk) or avoidable. In the former category, we include costs to which the firm is committed and
that must be paid regardless of any future actions of the firm. For instance, debt incurred to
construct a production facility must be repaid regardless of the facility's production plan and
even if the facility ceases operation prior to full repayment, unless the range of viable alternatives
includes declaring bankruptcy by the owners. The second category, avoidable costs, describes any
costs that are foregone by ceasing production. These costs can be further refined to distinguish
between costs that vary with the level of production and those that are independent of the
production level. For example, production factors such as labor, materials, and capital (except in
the short run) vary with the level of output, whereas expenditures for facility security and
administration may be independent of production levels but avoidable if the facility closes down.
Determining both the avoidability and the variability of firms' costs is essential to the analysis of
economic responses to the proposed regulations.
Figure A-8 illustrates the derivation of a facility supply function for a market pulp, paper,
or paperboard product from the classical U-shaped structure of production costs with respect to
output. Let AVAC be the facility's average variable (avoidable) cost curve and ATAC the
average total (avoidable) cost curve for producing the product. The vertical distance between
ATAC and AVAC is the per-unit average cost of nonvariable avoidable costs, and it approaches
zero as the number of units of output increases. MC is the marginal cost of producing paper,
paperboard, or market pulp, which intersects AVAC and ATAC at their respective minimum
points. All these curves are conditional on input prices and the technology in place at the
facility.
A-29
-------
$/q
pm _
Figure A-8 Product supply function at facility
A-30
-------
The facility supply function is the section of the marginal cost curve bounded by the
quantities qm and qM. qM is the largest feasible production rate that can be sustained at the
facility given the technology and other fixed factors in place, regardless of the output price. qm is
the minimum economically feasible production rate determined by the minimum of the AVAC
curve, which coincides with the price pm. Suppose the market price of paper is less than pm. In
this case, the firm's best response is to close the facility and not produce paper because P <
AVAC implies that total revenue would be less than variable costs if the facility operated at the
associated output levels below qm.
The nature of the pulp and paper production process typically implies that the manager
prefers to operate the plant at full capacity when producing output. This may at first seem to
contradict the notion of the U-shaped cost structure discussed above; however, rather than being
logically inconsistent, it is actually just a matter of what period of time is being considered in the
decision. We will describe the manager's decision of whether to operate at full capacity or not at
all as a very short run problem (daily or weekly), whereas the decision of how much to produce
over a longer period of time (e.g., a year) is an aggregation of these very short run decisions.
Since our model uses a year as the time unit of observation, it is the latter model we are
interested in. In order for that model to be consistent with U-shaped costs, successive very short
run operating decisions must involve successively higher operating costs beyond a certain point.
The reason average variable costs, and thus marginal costs, might rise with the number of
production days per year is found in the law of diminishing marginal returns—the classic cause of
U-shaped cost curves in economic theory. Beyond a certain level of operation (expressed in
terms of duration of days or level of production), the marginal product of variable inputs to
production diminishes given fixed plant and capital equipment. The corresponding marginal
costs therefore increase beyond that level of output or operating days.
In the case of the pulp and paper industry, factors contributing to this notion of rising
marginal costs might include the increased likelihood of machine failure—and thus reduced
productivity—as less down-time is available for maintenance, the potential for raw material
A-31
-------
shortages with less time to accumulate inventories, or reduced service lives of the physical capital
through higher rates of utilization, thus requiring more rapid replacement of the capital stock.
Now consider the effect of the proposed regulatory control costs. These control costs fall
into one of two,categories: avoidable variable and avoidable nonvariable. We characterized
these proposed costs as avoidable because a firm can choose to cease operation of the facility
and thus avoid incurring the costs of compliance. The variable control costs include the O&M
costs of the controls, and the nonvariable costs include compliance capital equipment.
The effect of these additional costs is illustrated in Figure A-9. The facility's AVAC and
MC curves shift upward (to AVAC1 and MC) by the per-unit variable compliance costs. In
addition, the nonvariable compliance costs increase total avoidable costs and thus the vertical
distance between ATAC and AVAC. The facility's supply curve shifts upward with marginal
costs, and the new (higher) minimum operating level (qml) is determined by a new (higher) pml.
Now consider the effect of compliance costs on the derived demand for inputs at the
regulated facility. Paper and paperboard manufacturing facilities are market demanders of pulp.
We can employ a similar neoclassical analysis to the one above to demonstrate the effect of
compliance costs on the demand for the market pulp input. Figure A-10 illustrates the paper
and paperboard manufacturing facility demand function for market pulp. Each point on the
derived demand curve equals the firm's maximum willingness to pay for the corresponding
marginal input. This is typically referred to as the input's value of marginal product (VMP),
which is equal to the price of the output (P) less the per-unit compliance costs (c) times the
input's "marginal physical product" (MPP), which is the incremental output attributable to the
incremental input. Ignoring any effect on the output price for now, an increase in per-unit
compliance costs due to the regulations will lower the VMP of all inputs by the unit amount of
the additional compliance costs, leading to a downward shift in the derived demand curve in
Figure A-10 (a) from D,- to D';.
The paper and paperboard manufacturing facility demand curve for market pulp is
downward sloping in this example, indicating that the marginal physical product of market pulp
diminishes as more is used to produce paper and paperboard, and substitution possibilities exist
A-32
-------
MC'
MC
ATAC'
AVAC1
ATAC
AVAC
qm qm' qM
q/t
Figure A-9 Effect of compliance costs on product supply function at facility
A-33
-------
$/qv
$/q\
-Dy
1
qy/t
qy/t
a) Without Fixed Input Coefficients
b) With Fixed Input Coefficients
Figure A-10 Effect of compliance costs on derived demand for market pulp at regulated facility
A-34
-------
with other inputs. If, as is assumed in this model, the input-output relationship between the
market pulp and the final paper and paperboard product is strictly fixed, not only by product
specification but also by constant efficiency of use at all input levels, then the VMP of the
market pulp is constant and the derived demand curve is horizontal with the constant VMP as
the vertical intercept, as shown in Figure A-10 (b).
The regulations will affect the costs of producing both market pulp and paper and
paperboard products. Because the markets are interrelated, paper and paperboard market prices
and quantities will be affected by changes in the market price and quantity of market pulp and
vice versa. These market linkages are described below.
A3.2 Market-Level Effects
For the purposes of this example, consider the relationship depicted in Figure A-ll
between the markets for a single paper or paperboard product, Q^ and a market pulp input, Qy.
Qy, along with other inputs, such as labor, energy, and chemicals, is used in the production of Qr
The competitive structure of the market is an important determinant of the regulations' effect on
market price and quantity. Below we show the market effects under the assumption of perfectly
competitive market structure for the pulp and paper industry.
We assumed that prices for the respective commodities are determined in competitive
markets (i.e., individual facilities have negligible power over the market price of the commodities
and thus take the price as "given" by the market). Under perfect competition, market prices and
quantities are determined by the intersection of market supply and demand curves. A market
supply curve is the sum of all facility supply curves, and a market demand curve is the sum of the
demand curves for all demanders of the commodity. The demanders of paper or paperboard
product, Qx, are final product consumers, and the demanders of market pulp, Qy, are the
individual facilities that purchase market pulp for producing paper and paperboard products.
Without the proposed compliance costs, the market quantity and price of paper or paperboard
product, Qx (Q^, P^), are determined by the intersection of the market demand curve (DJ and
A-35
-------
$/Qx
Px1
PxO
Dx
Qxi Qxo
(a) Market for Paper or Paperboard Product, Qx
$/Qy
Py2
Pyo
P/1
Qx/t
Qy1 Qy3 Qy2 QyO
(b) Market for Pulp, Qy
Qy/t
Figure A-ll Market equilibria with -and without compliance costs
A-36
-------
the market supply curve (S J, and the market quantity and price of market pulp, Qy (Qyo, Pyo), are
determined by the intersection of the market demand curve (Dy) and market supply curve (Sy).
Imposing the regulations increases the costs of producing pulp and, thus, paper and
paperboard, shifting the market supply function for both commodities upward to S'x and S'y,
respectively (see Figure A-ll). The supply shift in the market for paper and paperboard
.products causes the market quantity of each to fall to Qxl and the market price to rise to P^ in
the new equilibrium. In the market for pulp, the drop in the market quantity is unambiguous;
however, the direction of the change in the market price can only be determined if we know the
relative magnitudes of the demand and supply shifts. If the downward demand effect dominates,
the price will fall (e.g., P^), if the upward supply effect dominates, the price will rise (e.g., P^),
and if the effects just offset each other, the price remains unchanged (e.g., Py3 = Pyo).
The sign (positive or negative) of the effect of these market adjustments on commodity
prices and quantities is summarized in Figure A-12; the magnitude of these effects is an
empirical matter. The supply shifts for market pulp, paper, and paperboard cause the market
price to rise and market quantity to fall for these commodities at the new equilibrium. However,
the downward shift in the demand curve for market pulp will have an offsetting effect on price
leaving the total effect ambiguous, while exacerbating the effect on quantity resulting in an even
lower quantity produced. In both cases, the producers that are unaffected by the regulations
receive the higher price for their products without the associated increase in compliance costs
and thus increase their production levels.
Alternatively, if production cost savings are attributed to implementing pollution controls,
downward supply shifts for market pulp and paper and paperboard products and upward shifts in
the demand curve for market pulp are possible. The downward supply shifts will cause the
market price to fall and market quantity to rise for these commodities at the new equilibrium, as
displayed in Figure A-13. However, the upward shift in the demand curve for market pulp will
have an offsetting effect on price, leaving the total effect ambiguous, while exacerbating the
effect on quantity, resulting in an even higher quantity produced. In this scenario, the producers
that are unaffected by the regulations receive lower prices for their products and thus reduce
their production levels.
A-37
-------
Quantity
Increase Decrease
Increase
Price
Decrease
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
a) Market Pulp
Quantity
Increase Decrease
Increase
Price
Decrease
No
Yes
Yes
No
b) Paper and Paperboard Products
Figure A-12 Market adjustments for market pulp, paper and paperboard products
A-38
-------
$/Qx
Bco
Dx
Qxo Qxi
(a) Market for Paper or Paperboard Product, Qx
$/Qy
Qx/t
Dy
QyO Qyt
(b) Market for Pulp, Qy
Qy/t
Figure A-13 Market equilibria with and without compliance costs: cost savings attributed to
regulation
A-39
-------
A33 Facility-Level Response to Control Costs and New Market Prices
In evaluating the market effects for pulp, paper, and paperboard products, we must
distinguish between the initial effect of-the regulations and the net effect after all markets have
adjusted. Initially, assuming no production cost savings attributed to the pollution controls, all
affected facilities' supply curves for market pulp, paper, and paperboard shift upward by the unit
variable costs of the regulation. As a result, all affected facilities' derived demand curves for
market pulp shift downward by the unit variable control costs. However, the upward shift in the
industry supply curves for paper and paperboard pushes up the prices of those commodities,
which subsequently raises the VMP of the market pulp and, thus, puts upward pressure on the
derived demand for that commodity. In general, the initial upward shift in supply at the facility
will be greater than the subsequent increase in market price so that the mill reduces supply of
market pulp, paper, or paperboard. The initial downward shift in demand will typically dominate
the subsequent upward shift so that the net shift is downward and the mill reduces demand for
market pulp. However, determining which shift dominates for a particular mill is difficult: it
depends on the relative magnitude of the facility-specific unit variable costs of the regulation and
the changes in market prices.
Given changes in market prices and costs, mills will elect to either
Continue to operate, adjusting production and input use based on new revenues
and costs, or
Close the facility if revenues do not exceed total avoidable costs.
This decision can be extended to the multi-product facility where product lines may be closed if
product revenues are less than product-specific avoidable costs, and the entire facility may be
closed if total revenues from all products (market pulp, paper, and paperboard) do not exceed
facility-specific avoidable costs.
Thus, after considering the interaction of facility and market forces, we can derive the
production responses at each individual facility. The facility-level output effects can be
aggregated by mill type (pulp, paper, or integrated) to assess the distribution of production
A-40
-------
changes across different segments of the industry. Facility output effects can also provide
information on the employment impacts of the proposed regulations.
This approach to modeling the facility closure decision is based on conventional
microeconomic theory. It compares the ATAC—which includes all cost components that fall to
zero when production discontinues—to the expected post-regulatory price. Figure A-9 illustrates
this comparison. If price falls below the ATAC, total revenue would be less than the total
avoidable costs. In this situation, the owner's cost-minimizing response is to cease production.
An additional aspect of the facility-level impacts is the quantity adjustments. Changes in
costs will change producers' output rates. However, some of this effect is mitigated when prices
are increased. Of course, facility and product-line closures directly translate into quantity
reductions. However, the output of operating facilities will also change as will supply from
foreign sources. Affected facilities that continue to produce may increase or decrease their
output levels depending on the relative magnitude of the unit variable control costs and the
changes in market prices. Unaffected facilities will not face an upward shift in their product
supply curves, so their response to higher product prices is to increase production. This response
is illustrated in Figure A-14 as an upward movement along the facility's supply curve for the
product. Foreign producers, which do not incur higher production costs because of the
regulations, will respond in the same manner as these unaffected U.S. mills.
As mentioned earlier, if production cost savings are attributed to pollution control
measures at a facility, the facility's product supply curve will shift downward. This response is
illustrated in Figure A-15. The facility will enjoy lower costs of production because of the
regulations and will respond by increasing production, given current market prices. In addition,
recall that facility and market forces interact to determine the ultimate market adjustments and
facility responses. The changes in the price of market pulp, an input into the production of
paper and paperboard, will also affect the supply curves of facilities that produce paper and
papcrboard (i.e., paper mills and integrated mills that purchase market pulp). These indirectly
affected mills will face upward shifts in product supply curves if market pulp prices increase—a
result similar to mills facing increased production costs due to the regulations. Further,
A-41
-------
$/q
pm
,M
Qi/t
Figure A-14 Movement along the product supply function
A-42
-------
$/q
p* _
pm
«m
* *
Figure A-15 Shift downward in the product supply function
A-43
-------
indirectly affected mills will face downward shifts in product supply curves if market pulp prices
decrease—a result similar to mills facing decreased production costs due to the regulations.
The approach described above provides a comprehensive view of the effect of the
regulations on responses at the facility level as well as the corresponding effect on market prices
and quantities for the affected commodities. This approach is a substantial improvement over
analytical methods that do not account for facility-level responses such as quantity adjustments,
input adjustments, and closure of product lines or methods that ignore the effect of these
regulations on market prices when determining the change in revenues and costs at the facility
level. Methods that do not allow for production adjustments at the facility level essentially
assume that firms cannot or will not adjust to changes in production costs. No credible model
for changes in market prices exists unless it accounts for responses at the facility level. In reality,
firms do respond to market conditions and market price changes respond to regulations.
A.4 OPERATIONALIZING THE MODEL
To estimate the 'economic impacts of the regulations, we operationalized the competitive
market model of the pulp and paper industry outlined above. The purpose of the model is to
provide a structure for analyzing the economic impact of regulations to control the release of air
and water pollutants from chemical pulping and bleaching operations.
The model is a multi-dimensional Lotus spreadsheet incorporating the facility-specific
information on production obtained from the EPA's 1990 National Census of Pulp, Paper, and
Paperboard Manufacturing Facilities and model parameters characterizing domestic and foreign
(export) demands as well as foreign supply (imports). The model incorporates various data
sources to provide an empirical characterization of the U.S. pulp and paper industry and product
markets for a base year of 1989. We chose this base year of analysis because it is the last year
for which facility-specific production and technical data were available from the National Census
and for which supporting economic data were readily available. The model analyzes market
adjustments for 31 paper and papcrboard product markets and 6 market pulps by employing a
process of tatonnement whereby prices approach equilibrium through successive correction—
A-44
-------
modeled as a WalrasiaA auctioneer. Integrated facilities and paper-making facilities constitute
those facilities supplying final paper products; the pulp mills and those integrated mills involved
in the market for pulp, either as a supplier or demander, constitute those facilities included in
the model for market pulps. The model also includes a foreign trade sector with which to assess
the impact of international trade responses on market outcomes and vice versa.
To implement this model, we identified commodities and facilities to be included jn the
analysis, specified the supply and demand side of the market and associated response parameters,
specified the foreign trade sector and provided the corresponding response parameters,
incorporated demand and supply specifications into a market model framework, and evaluated
market adjustments due to imposing regulatory compliance costs and estimated the impacts.
This section discusses these activities.
A.4.1 Model Dimensions
Clearly the analysis must account for all marketable commodities involved in producing
pulp and paper, as well as all producers of these commodities. Figure A-16 illustrates the
modeled interactions between commodities and producers. The first marketable product is pulp,
either bleached or unbleached; the second marketable product is the final paper or paperboard
product. The model analyses the market adjustments for 6 market pulps and 31 paper and
paperboard products. AJ1 of these products are consumed and produced domestically, as well as
traded internationally. Therefore, domestic producers export some pulp and paper products to
other countries, and foreign producers supply their products to U.S. markets.
The pulp and paper industry is characterized by both nonintegrated and vertically
integrated mills. Nonintegrated mills include pulp mills that produce market pulp as well as
paper mills that purchase market pulp to produce paper and paperboard products. Vertically
integrated mills rely mostly on their own production of pulp to produce paper and paperboard
products. Those vertically integrated mills without enough internally produced pulp are also
demanders of market pulp, and those that produce an excess supply pulp of are suppliers of
A--45
-------
Domestic
Consumers
Foreign
(Exports)
C
PAPER/PAPERBOARD (31)
Integrated
Mills
(235)
Paper Mills
(303)
Foreign
(Imports)
Foreign
(Exports)
MARKET PULP (6)
Pulp Mills
(28)
Foreign
(Imports)
Figure A-16 Interactions between commodities and producers
A-46
-------
market pulp. We modeled the production from 566 pulp, paper, and paperboard manufacturing
facilities, including 28 pulp mills, 303 paper mills, and 235 integrated mills.
A.4.1.1 Commodities
EPA's 1990 National Census of Pulp, Paper, and Paperboard Manufacturing Facilities
identifies the mills existing in 1989 that may be affected by the air and water pollution
regulations. The detailed production data obtained from this source on each mill form the basis
for characterizing the commodities included in the model. Table A-7 lists the products with a
description of each product and its product code.
The National Census identifies 42 product markets to analyze—33 final paper and
paperboard products and 9 pulp products. However, National Census data on facility-level
production indicate no U.S. production of either other shipping sack (product code 32) or
hardboard (product code 52) in 1989. The markets for these product groups are not included in
the model; therefore, the model analyzes 31 paper and paperboard product markets.
Although some of the pulp product categories provided by the National Census
distinguish between bleached and unbleached pulps, not all pulp categories have this distinction.
Consequently, as shown in Table A-8, the pulp product categories were expanded to 17 to
account for bleached and unbleached versions of each pulp by matching the pulp category with
pulp process codes from the National Census. Bleached and unbleached pulps were categorized
using National Census data on the fiber source indicated by the pulp process codes and the
percentage of the fiber that is bleached and unbleached. Distinguishing the pulp products by
these features—pulping process and bleaching—is particularly important because the regulations
are aimed primarily at chemical pulping and bleaching. Thus, the model includes 17 pulp inputs
into the production of paper and paperboard.
Some subset of the 17 pulps described above are sold on the market (i.e., market pulps).
A number of the pulp inputs are only produced at integrated facilities for in-house production of
paper and paperboard products and are consequently not marketed. In addition, because some
A-47
-------
TABLE A-7
PULP, PAPER, AND PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS29'30> 31'32
Product (Code)'
Product Description
Pulp
Special Alpha and dissolving
woodpulp (1)
Sulfate-bleached (2)
Sulfate-unbleached (3)
Sulfite-bleached (4)
Sulfite-unbleached (5)
Groundwood-bleached (6)
Groundwood-unblcached (7)
Thermomechanical-bleached (8)
Thcrmomcchanical-unblcached (9)
Semiehemical-bleachcd (10)
Semicheniieal-unbleachcd (11)
Dcflbratcd or exploded-bleached
(12)
Defibrated or exploded-unbleached
(13)
Secondary-bleached (14)
Secondary-unbleached (15)
Cotton and rag pulp-bleached and
unbleached (16)
Chemical pulp from wood and other fibers with a very
high alpha cellulose content, readily adaptable for uses
other than paper and paperboard making.
Made from an alkaline pulp manufacturing process that
cooks chips in a pressure vessel using a liquor of primarily
sodium sulfide and sodium hydroxide with sodium sulfate
and lime being used to replenish these chemicals in
recovery operations (also kraft).
Made from acid pulp manufacturing process that cooks
chips in a pressure vessel using a liquor composed of
calcium, sodium, magnesium, or ammonia salts of
sulfurous acid.
Slurry produced by mechanically abrading fibers from
barked logs through forced contact with the surface of a
revolving grindstone. Used as newsprint and publication
paper.
Pulp made by presteaming chips and reducing them into
their fiber components during an initial mechanical
treatment in refiners under, elevated temperature and
pressure. Subsequent refining done at atmospheric
pressure.
Lower quality pulp made by cooking fibrous materials in a
neutral sodium sulfite-sodium carbonate liquor followed
by a final separation of the fiber using unpressurized
mechanical means.
Pulp made by thermomechanical process in which
woodchips are pretreated with a chemical, usually sodium
sulfite, either prior to or during presteaming as an aid to
subsequent mechanical processing in refiners.
Any type of paper- and paperboard-making fiber obtained
from \vastepapers and other used, reclaimable fiber
sources.
Pulp made from rags or cotton linters by a conventional
cooking process with lime and sodium hydroxide, followed
by refining and bleaching.
A-48
-------
TABLE A-7 (cont)
Product (Code)"
Product Description
All other fiber, n.e.c. (17)
Pulps other than wood such as pulp of fibrous vegetable
material (e.g., straw, reed, bagasse, bamboo, etc.); or
synthetic and semi-synthetic sources (e.g., glass, fiberglass,
rayon, nylon, combinations).
Paper
Newsprint (20)
Uncoated groundwood paper (21)
Clay coated printing and converted
paper (22)
Uncoated free sheet (23)
Bleached bristols (24)
Cotton fiber writing paper and thin
paper (25)
Unbleached kraft packaging and
industrial converting paper (26)
Special industrial paper, except
specialty packaging (27)
Tissue (28)
Wrapping (30)
Light, inexpensive grade made largely from mechanical
pulps and some unbleached sulfite or other chemical
pulps.
A higher grade than newsprint that is smoother and
brighter and used in newspaper inserts, catalogs,
paperback books, and directories.
Printing and converting papers that contain a layer of
coating material, such as clay or pigment, in combination
with an adhesive.
Contains no more than 10% mechanical pulps including
most grades of business paper, including forms, bond,
stationary, tablet, envelope, xerox, and computer paper,
and cover and text grades used in printing.
High quality cardboards used for products such as index
tags, cards, file folders, and postcards.
Papers in which cotton or other non-wood fibers comprise
25% or more of the total (e.g., bond, ledget, specialty
papers [also, rag]).
Various types of paper used for industrial or commercial
purposes, such as wrapping papers, bag and sack stock,
specialty papers.
Special industrial papers such as photographic sensitizing
paper, blotting paper, filter paper.
Light, fairly transparent, strong, absorbable, easily
disposable paper characterized by its gauze-like texture
made from mainly bleached kraft and sulfite pulps. Used
tor sanitary products.
Grade of non-sanitary tissue, all M.G. and M.F. wrapping
papers, treated and untreated butcher papers and
miscellaneous wrapping.
A-49
-------
TABLE A-7 (cont)
Product (Code)'
Product Description
Shipping sack (31)
Other shipping sack (32)
Paper made mainly from sulfate or soda, unbleached or
bleached woodpulp characterized by toughness and
strength, used in the manufacture of shipping sacks.
Rope and combination kraft and rope shipping sack
paper.
Other bag and sack (33)
Other bag and sack paper for
conversion (34)
Waxing stock (35)
Other (36)
Specialty packaging (37)
Glassine, greaseproof and vegetable
parchment (38)
Paperboard
Unbleached kraft (40)
Semichcmical papcrboard (41)
Recycled paperboard (42)
Wet machine board (43)
Construction paper (50)
All other kraft wrapping paper made mainly from sulfate
or soda, used in the manufacture of grocery bags and bags
other than shipping sacks.
Used for conversion in liquor, millinery, notion, or other
variety bags.
Packaging paper with weight over 29.4 g/m2
Other packaging and industrial converting paper such as
asphalting and creping stocks, coating and laminating,
gummed, twisting and spinning stocks (weight over 29.4
g/m2)
Packaging paper of weight not more than 150g/m2.
Papers made from pure chemical woodpulp or from
mixtures of chemical woodpulp, cotton fiber pulp, treated
by highly hydrated or hand beaten to render the resulting
paper resistant to oil, grease, and water.
High strength paperboard made from sulfate pulp, usually
with a naturally brown color from unbleached pulp.
Made from semichemical pulp, mostly used for
corrugating medium, which forms the inner, fluted layer
of cardboard and corrugated containers.
Made from a combination of recycled fibers from various
grades of paper stock, used for folding boxboard; core,
can, and tube grades, corrugating medium; and gypsum
linerboard.
Paper board manufactured using a paper machine
consisting essentially of a wire-covered cylinder rotating in
a vat of pulpstock on which a mat of varying thickness is
formed by drainage, such as binder's board and shoe
board.
Heavy paper used for watercolor and crayon artwork,
made in various colors primarily from groundwood pulp.
A-50
-------
TABLE A-7 (cent)
Product (Code)'
Product Description
Hardboard (51)
Insulating board (52)
Paperboard made resistant to water and ink penetration
by exposure to high degree of sizing treatments.
Paperboard used for insulating electric cables.
Bleached linerboard (60)
Folding carton type board (61)
Milk carton board (62)
Heavyweight cup and round nested
food container (63)
Plate, dish, and tray stock (64)
Bleached paperboard for
miscellaneous packaging (65)
Other solid bleached board (66)
Molded pulp products (70)
Kraft paperboard used to line or face corrugated core
board to form shipping boxes and various other
containers.
Type of boxboard made of bleached chemical woodpulp
and used in the manufacture of "folding type" containers
which are formed, filled, and closed by the user.
Special grade of bleached boxboard capable of being
converted into containers for milk, cream, and other
beverages.
Bleached paperboard used in the manufacture of cups
and other nested cylindrical containers, used for hot and
cold drinks and in packaging moist, liquid, and oily foods.
Bleached paperboard hard-sized for moisture resistance
and strength qualities.
Paperboard for miscellaneous packaging purposes such as
non-folding board for shipping cases and set-up boxboard.
Single-ply, homogeneous types of paperboards, made from
the same stock throughout the sheet structure, including
paperboard for moist, oily, and liquid foods.
Products including fruit and vegetable packs and egg
cartons.
*For all products termed bleached or unbleached: bleaching is the process if chemically treating
fibers to reduce or remove coloring matter so that the pulp is improved in terms of whiteness or
brightness and unbleached is produced without being treated with bleaching agents.
A-51
-------
TABLE A-8
PULP PRODUCTS, PRODUCT CODES, AND PROCESS CODES
Pulp Product
Special Alpha and
dissolving woodpulp
Sulfate-bleached
Sulfate-unbleachefl
Sulfite-bleached
Sulfite-unbleached
Groundwood-bleached
Groundwood-unbleached
Thermomechanical-bleached
Thermomechanical-unbleached
Semichemical-bleached
Scmichemical-unbleached
Defibrated or exploded-
bleached
Defibratcd or exploded-
unbleached
Secondary-bleached
j
Secondary-unbleached
Cotton and rag pulp-
bleached and unbleached
All other fiber, n.e.c.
Pulp Product
Code
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
National Census Process
Codea
A,D
C, W
C, W
B
B
H,J
H,J
G
G
E
E
I,F
I,F
K, L, M, N, O, P, R, S, T,
U,Y,Z
K, L, M, N, 0, P, R, S, T,
U,Y,Z
V
Q, X, SS
"Process codes taken from Subappendix, Table AA-1.
A-52
-------
of these pulps are traded in small quantities by a small number of suppliers, data were
insufficient to derive prices for some of these market pulp products. The U.S. Department of
Commerce's Current Industrial Reports: Pulp, Paper, and Board does not contain data on value of
product shipments and quantity of product shipped for a number of pulps because of disclosure
concerns. Thus, the model analyzes six market pulps:
• Special Alpha and dissolving woodpulp
• Bleached sulfate
• Unbleached sulfate
• Bleached sulfite
• Bleached secondary fiber
• Unbleached secondary fiber
A.4.1.2 Facilities
The pulp and paper industry is characterized by both nonintegrated and vertically
integrated mills. Nonintegrated mills include pulp mills that produce market pulp as well as
paper mills that purchase market pulp to produce paper and paperboard products. Vertically
integrated mills rely mostly on their own production of pulp to produce paper and paperboard
products. Mills producing low-value products are usually integrated, and mills making
specialized, high-value products arc usually nonintegrated. Technical integration (i.e., the
integration of pulp and paper manufacturing processes) can lead to savings in costs by reducing
pulp processing costs, transportation costs, and collective mill departmental and administrative
costs.
Each type of facility, integrated or nonintegrated, has a different decision to make
regarding production of pulp, paper, and paperboard. Accounting for the differences across mills
and modeling the decisions correctly for each type of mill allow for a more realistic portrayal of
the facility and, thus, market responses to the regulatory compliance costs. In this model,
A-53
-------
facilities are classified as either integrated or nonintegrated, and nonintegrated mills are broken
down further into pulp mills and paper mills. Therefore, we account for and operationalize the
different production decisions at each type of facility.
Integrated mills must determine optimal output given the market prices for all paper
products they produce, which will determine the amount of internal pulp to produce. Excess
supply of pulp will spillover into the market, while excess demand will cause the facility to
demand market pulp. For nonintegrated paper mills, the market prices for pulp inputs and final
paper and paperboard outputs will determine the optimal level of output to produce, and then,
the corresponding market pulp to purchase. For pulp mills, the price of market pulp will
determine the optimal supply of market pulp. The market supply of pulp is the sum of supply
from all market pulp suppliers, and the market demand for pulp is the sum of demand from all
market pulp demanders. The same is true for paper and paperboard products.
The economic model includes 566 pulp, paper, and paperboard manufacturing facilities
for which 1989 production and technical data were available from the National Census. As
mentioned in Section A.2.3, a total of 331 mills, or 58.5 percent, are nonintegrated. Paper-only
mills make up the vast majority of the nonintegrated classification (303 mills), leaving only 28
mills classified as pulp-only mills. The remaining 235 mills are considered integrated facilities
producing both pulp and paper on-site. This segment of the industry accounts for 41.5 percent
of all mills operating in 1989.
A.4.2 Domestic Supply of Pulp and Paper Products
Mills have the ability to vary output in the face of production cost changes. To allow for
mills to vary output in the face of regulatory control costs, we developed facility-specific, upward-
sloping supply curves for each product. The supply curves are specified over a productive range
with an upper bound given by facility productive capacity and a lower bound given by the
minimum economically viable output level at the facility.
A-54
-------
We describe the technology characterizing pulp and paper production at U.S. mills and
the corresponding supply functions and discuss the econometric estimation of the supply
relationships. We provide details on defining the product-specific production range at each
facility and explain how we incorporated the regulatory control costs into the model structure.
A.4.2.1 Production Technology and Supply Functions
For our analysis, we assumed the generalized Leontief technology to characterize pulp
and paper production at all mills. This formulation allows for estimating supply curves at the
mill level for each final good produced. Specification of the model includes 31 final paper
products, q;, with market price, p;; 17 fixed-proportion pulp inputs, qk; however only 6 are
marketable with price rk; and an aggregate measure of variable-proportion inputs — x, which
represents the variable inputs labor, energy, and chemicals with price I.
We assumed a Leontief, fixed-proportion relationship between paper and pulp — that is,
each unit of paper product q; requires aik units of qk. This fixed-proportions relationship
between the q;s and the qks implies that the firm's profit function, supply functions, and derived
demand functions depend on p; and r; only insofar as they depend on net price
n
Further, we assumed that the variable proportions input combines with pulp according to a
generalized Leontief technology, which is not fixed proportion. The supply functions for the
generalized Leontief technology may be derived via Retelling's lemma by differentiating the
profit function with respect to product price (sec Varian33).
In general, the supply function for paper products resulting from the generalized Leontief
technology with the assumption of no substitutability across final products (i.e., cross-price
elasticity of supply equal to zero for all mill outputs) is
where y^ and /3; are model parameters to be estimated econometrically, i indexes products, and j
indexes facilities. The theoretical restrictions on the model parameters that ensure that the
A-55
-------
(1)
profit function is convex in <£ and I and that the mill's supply curves are upward sloping are 7^ >
0 and $ < 0.
Equation (1) sets out the generalized Leontief functional form that is used to estimate
supply relations for three types of facilities: pulp mills, paper mills, and integrated mills. The
own-price variable is written as and is different for the three types of facilities. For a pulp
mill, the relevant supply price is r, the unadjusted price of market pulp. For integrated mills and
nonintegrated paper mills, the appropriate supply price is the net price,
n
The net price specification follows from assuming that a fixed amount of market pulp is required
for each unit of paper produced. The treatment of integrated mills views the internally
consumed pulp as an unobservable intermediate stage of production — the supply price is net of
market purchases of pulp. Thus, if the integrated mill purchased no market pulp, the
appropriate supply price is p, the unadjusted price of paper.
AA.2.2 Econometric Estimation of Supply Relationships
The upward-sloping product supply curve for each facility is econometrically estimated
using facility-specific data on production from the 1990 National Census of Pulp, Paper, and
Paparbourd Manufacturing Facilities and market prices obtained from U.S. Department of
Commerce data. Assuming generalized Leontief technology, as detailed above, the specification
of the supply function for a particular product to be estimated by ordinary least squares is
, j= 1, . . . ,N
t = 1985, 1988, 1989
(2)
A-56
-------
where qjt is production at facility j of the product in time period t, pt is the market price of the
product at time t, Ijt is a cost-share weighted index of the three components of variable costs
(labor, energy, and chemicals) that varies across facilities j and time periods t. Finally, let j>jt
represent the effects of unobserved variables that vary over j and t. The parameters to be
estimated are the facility-specific intercept (yj) and the product-specific coefficient (/?) on the
cost-price variable. Note that j is an index for facility, not product whose subscript has been
suppressed. This specification allows intercepts to vary across facilities but restricts their slopes
to be the same. The procedure can be thought of as pooling many (N) three-observation
regressions to estimate /S.
A.4.2.2.1 Facility-level production data. Production data in off-machine tons (OMT) of
market pulp, paper, and paperboard products at each facility in the industry for the years 1985,
1988, and 1989 were obtained from the 7990 National Census of Pulp, Paper, and Paperboard
Manufacturing Facilities?4 The production data for each mill were cross-checked with other data
available from the National Census to ensure accuracy. Such data included the fiber furnish used
in production, the bleached component of the fiber furnish, inter-facility product transfers, and
reported product shipments.
A.4.2.2.2 Market price data. Prices for market pulp, paper, and paperboard product were
imputed using data on value of product shipments and quantity of product shipped obtained
from the U.S. Department of Commerce's Current Industrial Reports: Pulp, Paper, and
Board.35-36-31 Market prices for the relevant years (1985, 1988, 1989) were calculated as
Market Price =
Value °f
,
Quantity
The market prices used for bleached and unbleached secondary fiber and molded puip
were not derived from this source. Instead the prices for these products were imputed from
National Census data using the above formula. For each year, we summed the value of
shipments for all mills producing the product and divided by the sum of all product shipments
A-57
-------
across those same mills. For each mill, the product of interest was the only marketed good
produced—ensuring that the calculations do not include the value or shipments of any other
products.
A.4.2.2.3 Cost-share weighted variable production cost index. The cost-share weighted index
of variable production costs, Ijt, was constructed from an average regional wage variable
computed as earnings per employee (wjt); the producer price index for fuels, related products,
and power (e,); and the producer price index for chemicals and allied products (ct). The Ijt
variable varies across time, as does each cost component, and across facilities, because of the
regional wage variable. The cost shares used to weight the variable cost components vary by the
three product types—pulp, paper, and paperboard. We computed the shares for each product
type from input-output accounts from the U.S. Department of Commerce as shown in Table A-9.
Before computing the cost-share weighted index, we normalized the producer price
indices for energy and chemicals to 1989 and converted the regional wage variable into a wage
index arbitrarily normalized to the southern region in 1989. This transformation allows each
variable to be measured in terms of a relative index for use in deriving the cost-share weighted
variable production costs index. The index was computed as
Jjt = 5W wjt + Seet + S°ct (3)
where Sw is the cost share for labor in the production of the product (pulp, paper, or
paperboard), while Se and S° are the corresponding cost shares for energy and chemicals. The
cost shares vary according to product (pulp, paper, or paperboard); thus, the index differs across
pulp, paper, and paperboard products. In addition, it is normalized relative to the southern
region in 1989 so that the index for mills located in the South in 1989 is equal to 100. Table A-
10 provides the indices used in the econometric estimation for each product by region and year.
AA.2.2A Facility-specific supply intercepts. Different intercepts were estimated for each
facility because of the lack of other independent variables to explain variation across mills in
production levels. Variables such as production capacity, mill size and age, productive efficiency,
A-58
-------
TABLE A-9
COST-SHARES OF VARIABLE PRODUCTION FACTORS
FOR PULP, PAPER, AND PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS38
Pulp
Labor
Chemicals
Energy
Total
Paper
Labor
Chemicals
Energy
Total
Paperboard
Labor
Chemicals
Energy
Total
Actual Cost
Share (%)
20.5
12.6
18.9
52.0
21.1
5.5
13.7
40.3
21.1
6.2
18.6
45.9
Modified Cost
Share* (%)
39.4
24.2
36.4
100.0
52.5
13.6
33.9
100.0
46.0
13.6
40.4
100.0
"Calculated as actual cost share for factor divided by total cost-share of all variable production
factors.
A-59
-------
TABLE A-10
COST-SHARE WEIGHTED INDEX OF VARIABLE PRODUCTION
COSTS BY PRODUCT REGION AND YEAR
Product/Region
Pulp
South
Midwest
Northeast
West
Paper
South
Mid-west
Northeast
West
Paperboard
South
Mid-west
Northeast
West
1985
101.909
98.298
97.589
105.166
101.777
96.965
96.020
106.116
103.999
99.792
98.966
107.793
1988
94.503
91.054
91.537
97.115
94.948
90.351
90.995
98.428
94.568
90.549
91.112
97.610
1989
100.000
98.356
97.227
102.289
100.000
97.809
96.305
103.050
100.000
98.084
96.770
102.667
A-60
-------
capital intensity, and investment would all be helpful in explaining the differences across mills,
but these variables or reliable proxies were not available from the 1990 National Census of Pulp,
Paper, and Paperboard Manufacturing Facilities or any other industry source at the facility level.
Therefore, we employed facility dummies to capture those otherwise unexplained differences in
production levels across facilities that are not accounted for through variation in variable
production costs and prices.
A.4.2.2.5 Supply parameters. A closer look at the econometric supply specification
requires interpreting the model parameters. Although the parameter /S for each product does
not have an intuitively appealing interpretation, it is related to the facility's supply elasticity for
the product—a well-known model parameter. The facility's supply elasticity for a particular
product, £jt, can be expressed as
3
-------
(6)
or
jt
./
(6')
Because economic theory dictates that the supply elasticity is positive (i.e., £jt > 0), and
q,,, p,, and Ijt are all positive, equation (6') above indicates that the parameter /S is negative (i.e.,
/5 < 0) for all products. Finally, the solution for /3 from equation (6') reveals the following
expression:
= -lit
(7)
Therefore, although the supply elasticity is not directly estimated by the econometric
specification of the supply function, we were able to derive the facility-specific supply elasticity
for each product via equation (61) given the estimated /S, market price, variable production cost
index, and facility's production level of the product. Unlike the product-specific ft the elasticity
is not constant but varies for a facility with qjt, pt, and Ijt.
An additional parameter provided by the econometric estimation of the supply function is
the intercept, y^, which varies across facilities. This parameter does not influence the facility's
production responsiveness to price changes as does the & parameter. Therefore, the 7-
parameter was used to establish production levels from the supply function (to be employed in
the economic model) that are consistent with those observed in the base year of analysis, 1989.
Thus. 7- was used to calibrate the model so that each facility's supply equation is exact using
1989 data. We explain the details of the calibration in Section A.4.5.
A.4.22.6 Results. The results of the econometric estimation of supply parameters are
summarized in Table A-ll. For 29 of the 36 product supply specifications, the estimated /3 is
A-62
-------
o
vcToo oCo
o\cs
oo in r- in
1
CA
C
oo
vocs
00
•e
eu
•*ri
C«
'"I
O
W
CO
H
CN OS »—< CO
OO i—' *O CN
|
en
O
ON
£•
3
•3
O.
•O
6fi
•C"
8,
(B
s
•o
s
Cu
a
a %
*^
-
bO
T3
U
«
8
D
•a
(U
"8
j
-g
*w
-
A-63
-------
4) 0
u .S
OS
•o
W
o
I
fa
duct (code
vo F-
o
oo
*l
>/•>
o -0
oooo
VO -0 OO •
•^ O >o
^oJ "l
com rt
VO •* r-l
^Crco
°ics '-i
«nvo oo
oo
VO
VO "_
cs O
^c^
voco
IO •
o
vort-
oo
ON
-------
cr
|
•
SQ
^^£
E-H
« "o
•M *<£5
U( (*g
&,«
^
fi
a
03
C
a
c*
IS
en
9
'•5*
"
2cs
OX) 4-^
cT o
.£ E
C/l *"""
8 H
0 g.
0^
°o. >o
0 l>
*» 1
1
£H C^
of °i
•^J* O
oo
1
CD
en
CN
VO
OO
VO
oo
CN
^—^
O
^r
(4-W
c3
ii
-£ u
II
ON T3
00 ^
r-^ o
o ^
1 "^
'-I T3
JRS?
£5 ^
en cs
r— 1
CN
S
c>
VO
1— I
ON
0
ON
^
•o'
rt
C
^
o
C.
c:
C.
"rt
"E
CJ
co
g^ gi^ 3^ j: A ^^
^»ON ^F^ £--0 ^--S Z >— '
§5 CN^ CN^CN^
1 **Ls ' sj^ ' ^^^
T~* *O tO "O CS ^"^ to *O ^ "^^
co x™vi oo ^^** to ?sr ^^^ ^^^ *"^i,
^o ^o to c*** ^o ^^ ^^ ^5 ^7
f"-*. i f^1* ^« C^l **—} VO •
en CN T-( r~- ' ^ TH
1— 1 1— 1 N-x
CN O CO f» <*
^ eo OO CN ~i.
m oo r~ oo i^
ON ON ON ON *~*
CD CD C5 C5
vo OO T- i VO <"
r— i rj- ON T— i d
O 06 «-5 O\
i — 1 l-H t-H
>— i vo co •
1 t 1
c° S S
•— • O bX)
JH •£ -S
3 J2 2
en C *Q
>S J UH
A-65
-------
ON O
"2 So cs
OO
co
oo o
CO
I
en
a
a
C4
ns
to
3
oo
oC
ON
o
vo
oo
o\
VO
O\
R
ON
C3
o
J
(O
*
b
CN
CO
CO
10
oo
CO
VO
00
VO
oo
oq
vo
vo
oo
ON
CN S
oo
CM
CN
CN
3
C
duct (code
vO
"2
CS
O
C
•o
c
3
•a
03
c.
0 X
o
o
•a
c
£ 5
O 1=
^•§ "
> 5 o
O 5 fS
3 -B -=
S g. 6
8
VO •— • N
00 CN
ON CO
vo* ^"^
•§• i-i
1 *-_ ~*
ON '""^
r~ ^j-
-2
t-~
oo
o
CN
in
CN
CO
CO
CO
3
•o
C.
£r
3
C-
T3
O
22
^
•c
OH
en
ts
3
T3
O
UH
OH
Xj
2
T3
CS
•o
C
CS
£»
'o
en
en
P
S
CS
C/3
•c
^
^"^
g
T3
*-*
8
_!>
_C3
'^
CS
T3
4~»
.2?
'53
£
03
.C
CO
«-"
8
CO
c3
T3
—
£H
^
"cS
_o
4»»
.£2
4^
CS
4—*
CO
.
^.
"oS
_o
4-*
CO
4~«
CS
4-1
CO
o
4^t
cS
e
1
•
4>
—
4-1
C
£^
cL
i — i
03
C
S
LC
1
CO
_>>
"cS
_o
4-J
y>
4-1
CS
4-*
CO
O
4-*
CS
.e
1
•o
en
•2^
CS
•s
en
U
1
X!
rt
S
"In
-------
negative and consistent with the theoretical value expected for this parameter. Furthermore, 17
out of the 29 estimates (58.6 percent) are significantly negative—as measured at an 80 percent
confidence level. With as many product groups as there are in the data set, sampling error is
certain to cause some estimated supply curves slope downward. Those products with positive
estimates for ft all suffer from a limited number of observations—all less than 30 observations.
Only one positive estimate of ft, that for bleached paperboard for miscellaneous packaging (65),
is significant at any reasonable level of significance.
The positive estimates of ft are not acceptable as inputs into the economic model because
they imply negatively sloped supply functions, which would lead to perverse model simulation
results. The method employed to provide acceptable ft parameters was to substitute the
production-weighted average market supply elasticity for successfully estimated products in the
same product code groupings (i.e., the 30s, the 40s, and the 60s). We then calculated the ft
parameters for products with positive econometric estimates by incorporating the appropriately
weighted market supply elasticity in equation (7). A summary of the ft coefficients used in the
economic model for each product and the corresponding market supply elasticity are provided in
Table A-12.
A.4.2.3 Estimating Product-Specific Production Ranges at Facilities
Figure A-17 illustrates a product supply function at the facility, which is the section of the
marginal cost curve bounded by the maximum and minimum quantities qM and qm. qM is the
largest feasible production rate that can be sustained at the facility given the technology and
other fixed factors in place, regardless of the output price. qm is the minimum economically
feasible production rate that is determined by the minimum of the AVAC curve, which coincides
with the price pm. If the market price of the paper product is less than pm, the firm's best
response is to close the product line because p < AVAC. This relationship implies that total
revenue from producing the paper product would be less than the corresponding total variable
costs of production at any level of output.
A-67
-------
TABLE A-12
PRODUCT-SPECIFIC BETA COEFFICIENTS AND SUPPLY ELASTICITIES
Product (code)
Market Pulp
Special Alpha and dissolving woodpulp (1)
Sulfate-bleached (2)
Sulfate-unbleached (3)
Sulfite-bleached (4)
Sccondary-blcachcd(14)
Secondary-unbleached(15)
Paper
Newsprint (20)
Uncoated groundwood paper (21)
Clay coated printing and converted paper (22)
Uncoated free sheet (23)
Bleached bristols (24)
Cotton fiber writing paper and thin paper (25)
Unbleached kraft packaging and industrial converting
paper (26)
Special industrial paper, except specialty packaging
(27)
Tissue (28)
Wrapping (30)
Shipping sack (31)
Other shipping sack (32)
Other bag and sack (33)
Other bag and sack paper for conversion (34)
Waxing stock (35)
Other (36)
Specialty packaging (37)
Glassine, greaseproof and vegetable parchment (38)
Supply
j8 Elasticity1
-408,318
-292,665
-84,012
-86,665
-239,065
-239,065
-669,183
-333,516
-3,736,643
-438,893
-997,887
-50,616
-197,787
-332,276
-777,387
-163,636
-238,335
N/A
-655,300
-458,630
-222,059
-108,326
-356,807
-262,312
0.2009
0.1856
0.2674
0.2320
0.7641
0.8211
0.2939
0.3304
1.6530
0.3087
1.2102
0.1 192
0.1858
0.9965
0.8156
1.6309
1.2618
N/A
1.6309
2.2533
1.6309
1.2049
1.6586;
1.6309
A-68
-------
TABLE A-12 (cont)
Product (code)
Glassine, greaseproof and vegetable parchment (38)
Paperboard
Unbleached kraft (40)
Semichemical paperboard (41)
Recycled paperboard (42)
Wet machine board (43)
Construction paper (50)
Hardboard (51)
Insulating board (52)
Linerboard (60)
Folding carton type board (61)
Milk carton board (62)
Heavyweight cup and round nested food container
(63)
Plate, dish, and tray stock (64)
Bleached paperboard for miscellaneous packaging
(65)
Other solid bleached board (66)
Molded pulp products (70)
Supply
ft Elasticity*
-262,312
-1,079,860
-401,789
-260,179
-31,802
-233,717
N/A
-129,821
-392,619
-1,480,241
-815,179
-271,920
-195,233
-404,756
-270,147
-46,986
1.6309
0.3158
0. 2757
0.4928
0.3545
0.8820
N/A
0.7406
1.0139
0.7481
0.4430
0.6807
0.6807
0.6807
0.6807
0.2382
•The product-specific supply elasticities were derived using equation (6') with the corrresponding
product-specific beta coefficient, product quantity (q) equal to the mean production level across
all mills in 1989, and the cost-share weighted index of variable production costs (I) equal to the
mean index across all mills in 1989.
A-69
-------
m
M
Figure A-17 Economctricaliy estimated supply function at facility
A-70
-------
A.4.2.3.1 Product-specific maximum capacity at facility. The facility and product-specific
intercept, 7-;, is the natural choice for the maximum production level of each product i at the
facility, qY- It represents the limiting value of quantity supplied as price becomes infinite,
A
-
oo \vs, + H_
hr h- = Til
because the value of the second term in the limit goes to zero as price approaches infinity. This
M
limiting value is shown in Figure A-17 as q • ^ = y^.
A.4.2.3.2 Product-specific minimum prices and quantities at facility. The area under the
product supply curve at the facility represents the facility's total variable costs of producing that
product. This area can be expressed as
yq =
(8)
where VQ is the total variable cost of producing product i, q* is the level of production of
product i at the facility, /j(qj) is the inverse supply function, and q? is the minimum economically
feasible production level at the facility, which corresponds to the price P™. The sum of VQ for
all final products produced at the facility represents the facility's total variable costs of
production (i.e., VCmill = f VQ for all products i) or
rc.m
!
i (?;)
-------
paperboard is reported by each mill in the EPA's 1990 National Census of Pulp, Paper, and
Paperboard Manufacturing Facilities.39 This figure represents the facility's total variable costs of
production, and integrating under the generalized Leontief supply function,1 given the above
relationships, we can express it as a function of q\ and q°:
VC.
\~^ 6 • I •
,'77=^-4-^
mill
(9')
where qj is known, while q™ is unknown. This is one condition in as many unknowns (q™) as
there are products at the facility.
The problem can be reduced further if we assume that q7 is proportional to base year
output, q|, by a factor k, so that
\, for all i.
(10)
The factor k is not related to product capacity at the mill; therefore, it is not a determinant of
the capacity utilization rate. This factor simply posits the minimum economically achievable level
of output to be the same fraction of current output for each product at the mill.
Thus, the facility's total variable costs can be expressed as
VC.
mill'
1 4
(9")
Product-specific q? and pf at the facility may be derived by solving equation (9") for the
unknown variable k and then backsolving through equation (10) to solve for qf and using that
result with the inverse supply function to solve for p™.
'See equation (1) in Section A.4.2.
A-72
-------
Applying this technique to the questionnaire data for each mill resulted in three different
outcomes, as summarized in Figure A-18. First, as shown in Figure A-18 (a), the value for k is
determined to be greater than zero and less than one (i.e., 0 < k < 1). Thus, the total variable
costs as measured by the area under the facility's product supply function matches the value
reported in the 1990 National Census for that facility. Second, in Figure A-18 (b), the value for
k is zero so that the minimum economically achievable output level also equals zero. Thus, the
total variable cost as measured by the area under the facility's product supply function is greater
than the value reported in the 1990 National Census for that facility. With k equal to zero, this
area represents the smallest possible value for total variable costs, which precludes matching the
reported number. Lastly, in Figure A-18 (c), the value for k is greater than one so that the
minimum economically achievable output and price levels are higher than the current output and
price levels. Thus, the total variable cost as measured by the area under thefacility's product
supply function is less than the value reported in the 1990 National Census for that facility. If k
equals one, this area represents the largest possible value for total variable costs, which again
precludes matching the reported number.
The first scenario calls for no adjustments because the calculated cost figure exactly
replicates the reported number at the mill. This scenario is true for 325 out of 566 mills
included in the analysis, or 57.4 percent. However, the other two cases necessitate some
adjustment because the calculated number does not replicate the reported number at the mill.
For the situation shown in Figure A-18 (b) with k = 0, the adjustments to fixed costs and other
revenue discussed below ensure consistency of the model cost estimates with reported cost
estimates from the 1990 National Census. This situation is true for 147 mills, or 26 percent of
the total.
For the situation shown in Figure A-18 (c), we assumed that the minimum economically
achievable level of output equals zero (i.e., k = 0) to calculate the area under the facility's
product supply curve. This assumption avoids erroneous baseline closure of product lines
(current output level less than shutdown level), as well as the selection of some arbitrary value
for k that will be instrumental in determining product line closures. We dismissed setting the
minimum economically achievable output level equal to the current output level after observing
profit levels for these mills from the 7990 National Census that were inconsistent with the zero
A-73
-------
qm q*
a) Model TVC Equal to Reported Value
P*
pm
= o q*
b) Model TVC Greater than Reported Value
q* qm
c) Model TVC Less than Reported Value
Figure A-18 Comparison of total variable cost measures
A-74
-------
profit condition implied by operating all product lines at the shutdown point. As before, after
setting k = 0, the adjustments to fixed costs and other revenue discussed below ensure
consistency of the model cost estimates with reported cost estimates from the 1990 National
Census. This situation applies to 94 mills, or 16.6 percent of the total.
A.4.2.4 Incorporating Regulatory Control Costs into Model Structure
The starting point for assessing the impact of the regulations on the markets for pulp and
paper products is to incorporate the regulatory control costs of each mill producing the products.
The compliance costs for each mill are estimated by Agency engineers and include the total
capital investment, the annual general and administrative costs, and the annual O&M costs
(variable costs).
The primary focus of incorporating regulatory control costs into the model structure is to
appropriately assign the O&M costs to the pulp products directly affected by the incidence of
control costs. In some cases this assignment is straightforward, such as the case of bleach plant
process changes or the case of bleach plant process vent controls. In these cases, the O&M costs
are shared by each bleached pulp product. Other cases are not as straightforward, such as the
case of end-of-pipe effluent controls. Because the costs of these controls are not readily
attributable to any specific production area of the mill, the costs are assumed to be shared by all
pulp products. The result of assigning the O&M costs to the pulp products produced by each
mill is a mill-specific per-unit production cost change for each of the 17 pulp products described
in Table A-8.
The secondary focus of incorporating regulatory control costs into the model structure is
to calculate the annual nonvariable cost of regulation-imposed controls. The annual nonvariable
control costs are determined from the net present discounted value (NPDV) of the stream of
after-tax cash outflows: the cash outflows are the total capital investment and the annual general
and administrative costs. The length of the stream of cash outflows corresponds to the average
length of the capital investment, which is estimated as 15 years, and the costs are discounted
using the facility-specific discount rate found in the National Census. The annual nonvariable
A-75
-------
control cost is then computed by annualizing the NPDV over the lifetime of the investment at
the facility-specific rate of discount. The annual nonvariable control costs enter the model at the
facility level, while the per-unit variable control costs enter at the product level for all facilities
affected by the regulations.
A.4.2.4.1 Product-level supply decisions at facility. The production decisions at the three
types of facilities — integrated paper mills, nonintegrated paper mills, and pulp mills — are affected
differently by the variable costs of control (i.e., the annual O&M costs). These direct costs are
borne by pulp producers, both suppliers of pulp to the market and to integrated mills that
produce and consume their own pulp. Because of the direct costs of control, market pulp prices
will rise, leading to indirect costs borne by nonintegrated paper mills and integrated paper mills
who purchase market pulp. The nonvariable control costs do not directly affect product-level
supply decisions except in the case of facility closure where supply is reduced to zero (see Section
A.4.2.4.2).
For integrated mills the variable costs of control associated with on-site production of
pulp will be borne at the level of paper and paperboard production. These costs, Cjk, are
expressed per unit of pulp and can be transmitted up to the paper product through the input
ratios. For example, the control costs at the paper level equal the sum of each pulp input's
n
control cost weighted by the on-site input ratio (a^^) that is, J^ a7i^cjk f°r aU
/C ~~ X
internally produced pulps used in the production of paper or paperboard product i. In addition,
*
the integrated mills will be indirectly affected by increases in the price of market pulp inputs.
These increases in pulp prices, Ar^ arc transmitted through the purchased input
n
ratios (ctj) that is, a-Ark for all market pulps used in the production of paper
product i. Therefore, the supply function for integrated mills is
A-76
-------
Further, although some nonintegrated paper mills may not be directly affected by the control
costs, they will be indirectly affected through the changes in the prices of market pulp inputs to
paper production. The supply function for nonintegrated paper mills is therefore expressed as
(12)
Pulp mills will be directly affected by the regulatory control costs, Cj,,, which enter as a net
price change to pulp producers (i.e., rk - Cjk). Thus, the supply function for pulp mills, assuming
the same generalized Leontief production technology is
(13)
The empirical specification of the market pulp supply equations of integrated mills and
pulp mills uses the unadjusted price of market pulp, which is the conceptually proper variable.
However, because of data limitations, the empirical specification of the paper and paperboard
supply equations of integrated and nonintegrated paper mills used the unadjusted paper and
paperboard prices rather than the price net of purchased pulp inputs. The effect this
has on the estimated supply parameters for paper and paperboard products depends on the
relationship between the variation in unadjusted price (ApJ and adjusted price
n
aikArk) over the period of observation.
A-77
-------
If the variation in unadjusted price is equal to the variation in adjusted price, then the
paper and paperboard supply equations of integrated and nonintegrated paper mills fully
captures the quantity response to the observed paper price and the unobserved market pulp
price. Intuitively, the variation is the same when the share of purchased pulp in production is
n
equal to zero (i.e., ^^ aik - 0 ) and\or market pulp prices are constant over this period of
time (i.e.,Ark = 0). Thus, the largest component of variation in the true net price must be
attributed to the change in observed paper price, Api5 as opposed to the change in the share-
n
weighted market pulp prices,
aikArk
k=l
If an integrated mill purchases no market pulp, the appropriate supply price is pi} the
unadjusted price of paper. However, integrated mills may purchase some portion of their fiber
furnish. Model data derived from the National Census indicate that integrated mills, as a group,
purchase 9 percent of their fiber furnish. Thus, the effect of using unadjusted price in their
supply relation is limited by the small amount of purchased pulp used in the production of paper
and paperboard products. Nonintegrated paper mills, by definition, purchase their entire fiber
furnish so that the appropriateness of the supply equation is determined by the variation in
market pulp prices. Although market pulp prices varied over this time period, the overall effect
on any one mill's supply relation may be mitigated by the combined effect of low (high) input
shares for purchased pulps with large (small) price changes. In addition, data on price changes
for individual market pulps over this time period indicate that offsetting price changes across all
purchased pulps used in production is also possible at nonintegrated mills.
Therefore, both the direct and indirect costs of control can be incorporated into the
supply relations as follows:
A-78
-------
Integrated paper mills:
Ju
Pi-
n
E aj
n 1
P AT + V a .°. c
iJ^k + JL ajiJtcik
lc=l 1
Nonintegrated paper mills:
Pi
n
Pulp mills:
A.4.2.4.2 Facility closure decisions. The discussion above assumes that producing pulp and
paper is profitable. However, a facility's optimal choice could be to produce zero output (i.e.,
close the facility). The facility may not always find complying with the regulation feasible and
thus may shutdown the pulp and paper manufacturing operations because it is no longer
profitable. We define the sufficient condition for production at the mill as nonnegative net
earnings before interest, depreciation, and taxes (EBIDT) (II), that is,
H = 77? - TC
(14)
where total revenue (TR) is the sum of product revenue (R(q)) and other revenue (R°), and
total cost (TC) is the sum of total variable production costs (C(q)) and total avoidable fixed costs
(FA). Post-regulatory net EBIDT are
IT = R(q) + R° - C(q) - C"(q) - FA- E
'KC
A-79
-------
where C"(q) represents the variable compliance costs at the mill and EKC represents the
annualized expenditure for compliance capital. The decision to operate requires non-negative
post-regulatory net EBIDT, i.e., nR ^ 0, which occurs when
R(q) + R° - C(q) -
or
- EKC
0
(15)
R(q)+R°-C(q) -.
7KC
(15')
In other words, a mill's net EBIDT before regulation must exceed the annual cost of compliance
(variable and nonvariable). This decision does not include an annualized value for the
liquidation opportunity cost, which is equivalent to assuming that the opportunity cost is offset by
costs of closing the facility.
A.4.23 Adjustments to National Census Facility-Level Data
The data reported in the 1990 National Census for a number of economic variables at
each mill had to be adjusted so that mill-level EBIDT in the model were consistent with that
imputed from the National Census. The economic model calculates 1989 revenue from pulp and
paper production for each mill as
31
= £
6
E
where the market prices for paper and paperboard products, pi5 and market pulp, rk, were taken
from the U.S. Department of Commerce's Current Industrial Reports: Pulp, Paper, and Board40
and the facility-level production of paper and paperboard products, q^, and market pulp, qjk, were
taken from the National Census. This estimate of product revenue is very similar to the reported
A-SO
-------
values from the National Census. In fact, the Pearson2 correlation coefficient, which reflects the
extent of a linear relationship between two data sets ranging from a value of -1 and 1, has a
value of 0.949 for these two variables. This value indicates a strong positive relationship between
the two measures of product revenue at each mill—a value of 1 would indicate that the measures
are exact (see Figure A-19).
In addition, the economic model calculates 1989 variable costs of production at each mill
according to the method outlined in Section A.4.2.3.2. Although we made every effort to
replicate the reported values in the National Census for variable production costs at each mill,
the two measures are not exact. The value of the Pearson correlation coefficient is 0.964 for
these two measures of variable production costs at each mill. As is the case for product revenue,
this value indicates a strong positive relationship between the two measures (see Figure A-20).
Given the 1989 values at each mill for product revenue and variable production costs, we
adjusted other revenue (from sources other than pulp and paper products) and total fixed costs
at each mill to approximate their reported EBIDT from the National Census. We derived
reported EBIDT from the National Census in the following way:
Pulp and Paper Total Nonmanufactunng
Product + Rgvenue - Manufacturing - Costsless
Revenue Costs depreciation
Using the reported value of other revenue at each mill in conjunction with the previous estimates
of product revenue and variable production costs, we calculated the implied base year value of
total fixed costs so that the profit at each mill in the economic model will exactly match the
reported EBIDT from the National Census. If the resulting estimate of total fixed costs is
2Given N observations of two variables x and y, the Pearson, or product moment, coefficient (r)
can be computed as
r =
where cov (x,y) is the sample covariance of x and y, and
sample standard deviations of each variable.
A-81
var(x) and Jvar(y) are the
-------
CO
1
O
I
100,000 200.000 300,000 400,000 500,000 600,000 700,000 800,000
Economic Model ($103)
Figure A-19 Production Revenue
A-82
-------
(0
«
a
§
o
600,000 j
500,000 • •
400,000 • -
300,000 - -
200,000 - •
•
100,000-j •'• *
••' • 5*.
100,000 200,000 300.000 400,000
Economic Model (S103)
500,000 600,000
Figure A-2Q Totaf Variable Costs
-------
negative (to match reported EBIDT), then total fixed costs are set to zero, and the absolute
value of the negative estimate of total fixed costs is added to other revenue in a lump sum
fashion. Thus, the base year value of total fixed costs at each mill as included in the economic
model is restricted to be greater than or equal to zero.
Furthermore, a number of mills lacked revenue and cost data from the National Census
to impute EBIDT. For these 41 mills, we calculated profit as the difference between 1989
revenue from pulp and paper production and 1989 variable costs of production. Thus, other
revenue and fixed cost at each of these mills are reported to be zero.
The resulting total revenue and total cost estimates in the economic model (after
adjusting other, revenue and total fixed costs at each mill) are very similar to the National Census
values reported for each mill. The Pearson correlation coefficient has a value of 0.966 for the
two measures of total revenue at each mill (see Figure A-21) and a value of 0.934 for the two
measures of total costs at each mill (see Figure A.-22). These values indicate a strong positive
relationship for each variable (i.e, the economic model closely resembles the characterization of
each mill as determined by the National Census).
A.4-3 Domestic Demand For Pulp And Paper Products
A.4.3.1 Market Pulp
The model does not specify an exogenous demand function for market pulps because that
demand is derived from the paper supply decisions at the integrated and paper mills.3
3SpcciaI Alpha and dissolving woodpulp is not only an input into the production of paper and
paperboard products, but also in the production of other commodities. We solved,for the
consumption of this pulp by industries other than the pulp and paper industry using the following
equation:
Consumption by _ US.
Other Industries ~ Production
Consumption by
Imports - the Pulp and
Paper Industry
A-84
-------
c
T—
CO
3
CO
c
V
O
"53
c
O
co
Z
800,000 -
700,000 -
i
600,000 •
500,000 -
400,000 •
300,000 •
f^f\f\ f\f\f\ •
200,000
100,000 -
• ^^f
• • ss
"./• '
[ i*.-
m J' •
Sz
«^» • * * *
? *x^«*»* c*
• • *&/***
• * <^A fi/^» • •
•.y«28*«""
o >
0 100,000 200,000 300,000 400,000 500,000 600,000 700,000 800,000
Economic Model ($103)
Figure A-21 Total Revenue
A-85
-------
to
700,000 T
eoo.ooo • r
100.000 200,000 300,000 400,000 500,000
Economic Model ($103)
600,000 700,000
Figure A-22 Total Costs
A-86
-------
c
Therefore, once the paper and paperboard production decisions (0..) at each mill have been
made, the mill-specific purchased input ratios for each market pulp (aL) will determine the
domestic demand for each market pulp q£ as
Internal consumption of pulp is determined by mill-specific on-site input ratios for each pulp
input (a^,) . These on-site input ratios also form the basis for transmitting the variable
juc
compliance costs expressed per unit of pulp produced at the mill (cj^) to per-unit variable
compliance costs at the level of paper and paperboard products (Cjj), that is,
" 0
C~ = 2J a-jf c-k for °U PaPer and paperboard products (/) .
k=l
We deriyed the mill-specific purchased input ratios for each market pulp and the mill-
specific on-site ratios for each pulp input from technical production data obtained from the
National Census. We assumed these ratios to be constant throughout the analysis, thereby
restricting each mill to produce paper and paperboard products with the same combination of
fiber sources, in the same relative amounts, both before and after imposing the regulations.
The model assumes the integrated mills that met all pulp input needs through on-site
production in 1989 will not be active on the markets for pulp and will continue to satisfy all pulp
requirements internally after imposing the regulation. Thus, these mills are neither suppliers nor
dcmandcrs in the markets for pulp. However, the model does account for the interaction of
those integrated facilities that were active in the pulp markets during 1989, by specifying supply
relationships tor market pulp suppliers, or by specifying purchased pulp input ratios for market
pulp demanders.
This approach indicates that 634,286 (short) tons of this woodpulp were consumed by other
industries in the United States. The domestic demand is determined as in equation (18) with the
domestic demand elasticity estimate reported in Table A-14 and the constant parameter solved
for in a similar fashion as that for paper and paperboard products.
A-87
-------
A.4.3.2 Paper and Paperboard Products
The model specifies a general formula for the domestic demand for each paper and
paperboard product (q*-), that is,
where Aj is a positive constant and ???, the demand elasticity, is negative. This specification is
consistent with a constant elasticity demand curve that is derived via simultaneous equation
estimation in logarithmic form. Thus, we used the econometric estimate of the demand
elasticity, ijf, for each paper and paperboard product in this demand specification and determines
the responsiveness of quantity demanded to changes in paper product price. The product-
specific demand parameters, A;, were determined through backsolving techniques to calibrate the
model so that base year supply equals base year demand for all paper and paperboard products
as discussed in Section A.4.5.2.
A.4.3.2.1 Econometric estimation of domestic demand relationships. Recall from our
discussion of the "auctioneer" market model that each time the mythical auctioneer offers a new
price for each product, each firm offers its profit-maximizing quantity at that price. Summed
across firms, this quantity equals the market supply response to the price. On the demand side
of the market, we need to adjust the quantity demanded in response to the new price. This
adjustment can be expressed in terms of a demand function
QJ = Q1 (P,Z)
where quantity demanded, Qd, is a function of price, P, and Z, other demand factors such as
income or the price of substitute goods. The responsiveness of quantity demanded to a change
in price can be characterized by the demand elasticity .
This demand elasticity measures the proportional change in quantity demanded given a
proportional change in price. Economic theory suggests that t\ is negative (i.e., a rise in price
A-KS
-------
dQd
. Qd
dP_
T
should induce a reduction in quantity demanded, all else equal). The absolute value of a
product's demand elasticity measure is often compared to a benchmark value of one. An
absolute value of 17 greater (less) than one indicates that demand is elastic (inelastic) with respect
to price.
In this section we describe the underlying model of product demand, the econometric
method used to estimate the product demand functions, the data employed in the analysis, and
the resulting product demand elasticities.
A.4.3.2.1.1 Specifying the demand function. We generated values of r\ for each paper
and paperboard product by specifying a market demand function for each product, with quantity
demanded as a function of price and other factors, and by econometrically estimating the direct
effect of price on quantity demanded through this functional specification. The general form of
the demand function is specified
m
3, Ln (PJ
Ln
(19)
The i subscript indicates the product, the t subscript indicates the time period of
observation, and the j subscript indexes m. other demand variables. The error term, j>it, reflects
the nonsystcmatic random factors that affect observed demand quantities in each period.
Because we specified the natural log of the quantity as a linear function of the natural log of the
price, the value ,we derived for the parameter, £,,, gives an estimate of the demand elasticity, 7j;.
A.4J.2.1.2 Estimating the demand function. At first glance, estimating the demand
function seems like a simple procedure of regressing the observed market quantities on the
A-S9
-------
observed market prices and other demand determinants indicated in equation (19).
Unfortunately the task is not so straightforward. We must account for the fact that the observed
prices and quantities are equilibrium values, which are determined by the simultaneous solution
of the separate market demand and supply functions. We elaborate on this point here to
correctly specify the system for econometric estimation.
A partial equilibrium market supply and demand model is specified as a system of
interdependent equations in which the price and output of a product are simultaneously
determined by the interaction of producers and consumers in the market. We can define the
supply and demand system for a particular product as follows:
Qi"=f(P,Z!)+ui
(20)
=
Q? = Q
(21)
(22)
Equation (20) is analogous to equation (21), representing quantity demanded as a
function of price, P;; an array of demand factors, Z;; and an error term, u;. Equation (21)
represents quantity supplied as a function of price and other supply factors, Wj (e.g., input
prices), and an error term, v;. Equation (22) specifies the equilibrium condition: quantity
supplied equals'quantity demanded. Thus we have a system of three equations, which include
three variables. The interaction of the specified market forces solves this system, generating
equilibrium values for the variables. P' and Oi"=Q,d*=Qi*".
Variables that arc determined within a system, such as P;" and Qj", are said to be
endogenous to that system, while those that arc determined outside of the system, such as Z; and
W;, are called exogenous. In simultaneous equation models, endogenous variables are correlated
i
with the error terms through solution of the system. As a result of the interdependence of the
endogenous variables and the error terms, we must modify the application of standard regression
techniques to estimate the effect of an endogenous right-hand side (regressor) variable (i.e.,
equilibrium price) on the endogenous left-hand side quantity demanded (or supplied) variable.
A-90
-------
In general, ordinary least-squares estimation of the individual equations in the market model
leads to biased and inconsistent parameter estimates when a regressor is endogenous.
An additional consideration is that the supply and demand equations must be
econometrically identified, which means that the relevant values of the structural parameters
(e.g., the price elasticity of demand in this case) can be obtained from the estimated equation.
To identify an equation in a simultaneous system, the number of exogenous variables excluded
from the equation must exceed the number of included endogenous variables minus one. This
situation is referred to as the order condition for identification. Because both equations (21) and
(22) have two included endogenous variables (Pj and Qi), the order condition requires that each
equation must also include at least one exogenous variable that is not included in the other
equation. This condition is satisfied by the distinction between exogenous demand factors, Zj,
and exogenous supply factors, W; in equations (20) and (21). Note that the order condition is a
necessary, but not sufficient, condition for identification. The sufficient condition for
identification ist the rank condition, which tests whether the equation in question could be
constructed from a linear combination of other equations in the system. If so, then the equation
is not uniquely identified.
Endogeneity bias is corrected by applying the two-stage least squares (2SLS) regression
procedure for each equation estimated (see, for example, Pindyck and Rubinfeld41). Because the
objective was to generate estimates of the demand -elasticities, we estimated only the demand
function for each1 market. In the first stage of the 2SLS method, the price observations were
regressed against all exogenous variables (Z^W;) in the system. This regression produced fitted
(or predicted) values for the price variable that are, by definition, highly correlated with the true
endogenous variable and the observed price and uncorrelated with the error term. In the second
stage, these fitted values were employed as observations of the right-hand side price variable in
the demand function. This fitted value is uncorrelated with the error term by construction and
thus does not incur the endogcneity bias previously mentioned. The second-stage parameter
estimate for price provides the elasticity estimate indicated by equation (19).
For the purposes of domestic demand estimation, the dependent variable is domestic
consumption of product i (in tons), which equals domestic production less exports plus imports:
A-91
-------
f= Qi* - Q? + 0," •
(23)
Likewise, the value of domestic consumption equals the value of domestic shipments less value of
exports plus value of imports:
(24)
We computed the consumption price of the product as domestic consumption value divided by
domestic consumption quantity:
In general, imports and exports are reported at higher levels of aggregation than the
product groups identified in the National Census. For instance, paper products 30 through 37
are summed together in the import and export data, as are products 40 and 42 and 60 through
66. Because we needed domestic production, import, and export values to compute domestic
consumption, we aggregated the domestic production data according to these import and export
aggregations.
Once the product groups were aggregated, we computed the prices and quantities as
specified above. As discussed above, the first stage of the 2SLS procedure involved regressing
the observed price against supply and demand variables that are exogenous to the market. On
the demand side, these variables included GNP and population for the U.S. while the supply-side
variables included the separate prices of labor, materials, and energy faced by the paper and
paperboard industry. All prices employed in the estimation process were deflated by the
consumer price index (CPI) to reflect real, rather than nominal, prices.
In addition to price, other potential demand variables included CPI-deflated Gross
National Product as a measure of economic activity and separate price indices for fuels, plastics
and rubber, and lumber as measures of substitute product prices. The right-hand side variables
arc not the same for all. equations, which allows for some product-specific differences. For
example, the fuels price index is specified as a demand factor for insulating board (product 52),
A-92
-------
and the plastics and rubber price index is included in the demand equations for packaging and
industrial converting paper (products 30 through 37) as a proxy for the price of substitute
packing materials.
A.4.3.2.1.3 Data sources. Annual value of shipments and quantities produced by
domestic producers for each of the product groups are reported in the U.S. Department of
Commerce's, Current Industrial Reports: Pulp, Paper, and Board *2-43-44-45-464 The domestic
shipments data are available for the years 1981 through 1989. The corresponding annual values
for imports and exports are reported in Statistics of Paper, Paperboard, and Wood Pulp, published
by the American Paper Institute.50-51
The labor price facing the paper and paperboard industry was derived using annual data
from the. Annual Survey of Manufactures52-53-S4> S5> 56 for the paper sector (SIC-2621) and
paperboard sector (SIC-2631). We computed this value by dividing total compensation
(including mandated and other employer-paid benefits) by total labor hours. Total annual labor
hours equals the sum of production hours and nonproduction hours, the latter estimated as the
number of nonproduction employees multiplied by 2000. The Producer Price Index for
intermediate supplies and materials served as a proxy for materials price for the paper and
paperboard industry, while the producer price index for fuels served as the proxy for energy
price.37 Annual figures for the Producer Price Indices of substitute commodities, as well as the
CPI were taken from the Handbook of Labor Statistics and the Survey of Current Business.5*-59
U.S. Gross National Product figures were also taken from the Survey of Current Business.60
A.4.3.2.1.4 Results. Because the domestic shipments data for these categories are only
available for 1981 through 1989, we were limited to nine observations for each equation. This
"Production data for product category 70, molded pulp, are from the 1982 and 1987 Census of
Manufactures: Converted Paper and Paperboard Products, Except Containers and Boxes (years 1981 -
1986)47-4* and the 1990 Annual Sun-ey of Manufactures, Value of Product Shipments (years 1987 -
1989).49
A-93
-------
situation constrained the number of explanatory variables we specified for each equation because
of statistical inference considerations related to the degrees of freedom of the estimated model.
Table A-13 provides domestic demand elasticity estimates along with the associated t-
statistics, marginal significance levels (i.e., probability values for the t-statistics), and list of
regressors. Note that a number of closely related products share the same elasticity estimate
because of the data aggregation discussed above. Various specifications of the demand functions
for products 24 and 26 performed poorly in estimation and are not reported here. Because of a
lack of data, we provide no estimate for product 70. Consequently the estimates for similar
products are used in place of direct estimates for these three product groups. The estimate for
product 25 is used for product 24, the estimate for 27 is used for 26, and the estimates for
products 60 through 66 are used for product 70. The elasticity estimates for all products are of a
magnitude similar to other industrial commodities, ranging from -0.232 for product 23 to -2.930
for product 52: most estimates fall in the -0.5 to -1.5 interval. The t-statistics are fairly strong
for a large number of the products. This level of significance is particularly true for the
paperboard estimates (40-66), most of which are significant at an 85 percent level of significance
or better.
A.4.4 Foreign Sector
The importance of including a foreign sector in the economic model is highlighted by the
significant level of international trade of products manufactured by facilities in the U.S. pulp and
paper industry. Section A.2.5 provides detailed information on the extent of foreign supply of
pulp and paper products to the U.S. (imports) and foreign demand for U.S.-produced pulp and
paper products (exports).
The model specifies a general formula for the foreign supply for each market pulp (q£)
arid paper and papcrboard product (q{):
A-94
-------
TABLE A-13
DOMESTIC DEMAND ELASTICITIES-PAPER
AND PAPERBOARD PRODUCTS
Product Code*
Paper
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
30-37
38
Paperboard
40,42
41
43
50
51
52
60-66
70
Elasticity
Estimate
-0.301
-1.135
-1.839
-0.232
-0.647
-0.647
-1.907
-1.907
-0.574
-1 .937
• -0.894
-0.235
-0.353
-1.032
-0.940
-0.259
-2.930
-0.752
-0.752
t-statistic
-1.087
-1.192
-3.371
-0.987
-1.055
-1.055
-0.920
-0 .920
-0.517
-1.630
,2.770
-1.407
-2.198
-4.644
-1.760
-0.718
-0.981
-2.280
-2.280
Prob-val
0.32
0.28
0.02
0.37
0.33
0.33
0.40
0.40
0.63
0.16
0.03
0.22
0.07
0.01
0.13
0.50
0.38
0.07
0.07
Regressors
P, GNP
P, GNP
P, GNP
P, GNP
P, GNP
P, GNP
P, GNP
P, GNP, time
P, GNP, PPI-plastics
P, GNP, PPI-plastics
P, GNP
P, GNP, PPI-lumber
P, GNP
P,GNP
P,GNP
P, GNP
P, GNP, PPI-fuels
P, GNP, PPI-plastics
P, GNP, PPI-plastics
'Product names and descriptions corresponding to the product code are given in Table A-7.
A-95
-------
/ - fi'frf*
*k ~ Bj£i\
(25)
and
(26)
where Bj and B| are positive constants and Q and f { are positive measures of the foreign supply
elasticities for market pulp (k) and paper and paperboard products (i).
The model also specifies a general formula for the foreign demand for each market pulp
(qj) and paper and paperboard product (q*):
(* (27)
and
(28)
where A£ and A* are positive constants and ijj and ij* are negative measures of the foreign
demand elasticities for market pulp (k) and paper and paperboard products (i).
Numerically computed, rather than cconornetrically estimated, elasticities of import
supply and export demand for each of the pulp and paper commodities were used in these
foreign supply and demand specifications and determined the responsiveness of foreign trade
flows to changes in product prices. The multiplicative product-specific foreign supply and
demand parameters, Ax and B', were determined through backsolving techniques given estimates
of the import supply and export demand elasticities, 1989 baseline prices, and product-specific
quantities of U.S. imports and exports for 1989 (sec Section A.4.5 for further details on model
calibration).
A-96
-------
The next section describes the methodology for obtaining the key parameters—the import
supply and export demand elasticities—necessary for including the foreign sector in the economic
model.
A.4.4.1 Computing Import Supply and Export Demand Elasticities
To evaluate the full economic effect of changes in the cost structure for U.S. pulp and
paper producers, we must consider the role of international trade. A regulation-induced increase
in the U.S. price for a product can be expected to attract imports and reduce exports of that
product, all else equal. In this section we describe the methods used to derive the elasticities of
import supply and export demand for each defined product. .
A.4.4.1J Specifying the model. The difficulty of econometrically estimating import and
export elasticities from international trade data has long been recognized. Orcutt demonstrated
that elasticity estimates derived from regressions of a country's import (export) quantity on
historical prices understate the true price responsiveness of imports and exports, typically by a
substantial magnitude.61 Part of the difficulty derives from the identification problem, described
above, which is more pronounced given the difficulty in procuring measures of exogenous
demand and supply factors for foreign consumers and producers. Orcutt demonstrates how to
derive the total elasticity of imports and exports, which accounts for the effect of the change in
price on all (foreign and domestic) producing and consuming parties. We develop that method
i
here to numerically compute, rather than econometrically estimate, the elasticities of import
supply and export demand for each of the pulp and paper commodities in the study.
For the purposes of this example, consider country A, who internally produces some
portion of a product it consumes and imports the rest from country B. Let the U.S. be country
A. Country B can either be an aggregate entity (i.e., the "rest of the world") or a specific country
such as Canada. -Assume here that country B exports to the U.S. only; the rest of production is
consumed internally in country B.
A-97
-------
Imports to country A equal A's excess demand for the product.
o A =
!eJm
- QA(P)
(29)
where P is the price of the good in country A.
Exports from country B equal B's excess supply of the product
QB = QB(pB) . QB (fB) (3Q)
where PB is the price in country B. In equilibrium, the home price received by the country B
exporter should just equal the net price received from exporting to country A.
P* = XP -1
AB
(31)
where X is the exchange rate and t^ is the transportation cost (and any tariffs) between A and
B. In this example, country B's exports must equal country A's imports in equilibrium.
os = a
(32)
We now want to evaluate the effect of import supply with respect to a change in country
A's price (e.g., as a result of regulations on country A's producers). The supply elasticity of
imports is defined
emA = (dQmAldP)(PIQm«) . (33)
By manipulating the trade equations above, we get the following expression for the
import elasticity:
<-«„," =11 + (UP")] A'/ (Q"/Q S) - edB(QdBIQmA)J (34)
A-98
-------
where esB and edB, respectively, are the supply and demand elasticities for country B's producers
and consumers.
For demonstration, let the following values hold: esB=0.5, e^ = -1.0, QSB= 40, QdB=20,
which implies QmA = 20. Suppose transport costs to country A are 20 percent of the country B
price. Inserting these values into the elasticity equation yields emA = 1.6, which is more than
three times the "regular" supply elasticity. This difference would be even more pronounced if a
smaller portion of country B's product was exported or if transport costs were a larger portion of
the price.
Similarly, we can compute the elasticity of export demand facing country B. Because we
are interested in the export demarid for U.S. products, country B is the U.S. in this scenario and
country A is the foreign entity (rest of the world or a specific country). After manipulating the
trade equations, we get the following expression for the export demand elasticity:
e =
(OS/OS) - e?(Q,AIQ*B)]
(35)
where esA and edB, respectively, are the supply and demand elasticities for country A producers
and consumers. Let the supply and demand elasticities be the same in country A as they are in
country B (0.5, -1.0), and let country A's demand and supply quantities be QdA=100 and QSA=80,
which is consistent with Qx"=20.
Inserting these values into the elasticity equation yields exB = -8.75, which is almost nine
times the "regular" domestic demand elasticity. This difference would be even more pronounced
if a smaller portion of country A's demand was satisfied with exports from country B or if
transport costs were a smaller portion of the price.
The underlying message here is that theory strongly suggests foreign trade elasticities are
larger than domestic elasticities, much like the elasticity facing a single producer or consumer is
larger than the elasticity facing the aggregate of consumers and producers (the market). This
theory is borne out in empirical work as well. For instance, a study of the supply of wheat for
consumption in Japan estimates that the short-run import supply elasticity for Japan is more than
A-99
-------
400 times the magnitude of the "regular" supply elasticity for world wheat producers.62 We
explain the logic behind this using the example of import supply to country A. When the price
in country A rises, the A market looks marginally more profitable for B's producers. They will
respond by shifting supplies to country A's destinations until marginal supply units are equally
profitable for each destination (i.e., a new [higher] equilibrium price is established in Country B)
via equation (31). In the transformation to the new equilibrium, country B consumers demand
less as the price they pay rises, and country B producers produce more as the price they receive
rises. Exports to country A rise by the amount of the increased production by B's producers plus
the reduced consumption of B's consumers (i.e., by the growth in excess supply). The
proportional effect, as implied by the elasticity in equation (34), is larger if exports from B to A
are small relative to B's production (and B's consumption). At the limit, these elasticities are
infinite, indicating the textbook case of price-taking in world markets by small open economy
producers and consumers.
A.4.4,1.2 Computation procedure. To compute the foreign trade elasticities for the U.S.,
we must specify who plays the "role" of the foreign entity in the analysis, that is, who are the
foreign (country B) producers and consumers in constructing the import supply elasticity,
equation (34), and the foreign (country A) producers and consumers in constructing the export
demand elasticity, equation (35).
As previously mentioned, the foreign entity can be perceived as one country in the case
of bilateral trade or the rest of the world in the case of multilateral trade. For a number of pulp
and paper products (e.g., newsprint imports), U.S. trade is almost entirely bilateral with Canada,
while for other products (e.g., linerboard exports), U.S. trade is essentially multilateral.63 In the
case of import supply to the U.S., we have
where cmc is the import supply elasticity using equation (34) with Canada as country B (the
source of U.S. imports), Smc is the Canadian share of U.S. imports, emR is the import supply
elasticity using equation (34) with the rest of the world as country B, and SmR is the rest of the
A- 100
-------
world share of U.S. imports. For the purposes of this study, the rest of the world includes all
OECD countries excluding the U.S. and Canada.
Likewise we computed a weighted average for the demand elasticity for U.S. exports:
where e,0 is the export demand elasticity using equation (35) with Canada as country A (the
destination of U.S. exports), Smc is the Canadian share of U.S. exports, exR is the export demand
elasticity using equation (35) with the rest of the world as country A, and SXR is the rest of the
world share of U.S. exports.
A.4.4.1.3 Data sources. Data on production and consumption of pulp and paper
commodities by each country in the OECD for 1989 are found in The Pulp and Paper Industry in
OECD Countries.M Tables in that publication report trade flows (imports and exports) to and
from each of the member countries and the OECD in aggregate for 30 different pulp, paper, and
paperboard product groups. These tables also report total production, consumption, imports,
and exports for each country and the OECD aggregate for each product. From these tables we
computed the foreign and domestic ratios implicit in equations (34) and (35) to compute the
Canadian and rest of world elasticities. The product groups classified by the OECD were
matched up with the product categories specified for this study to the extent possible. Because
the OECD classification includes fewer groups, sometimes we had to use the foreign and
domestic ratios from one OECD category as representative of that ratio for more than one of
the product categories defined for this study.
We used the U.S. demand elasticity estimates, described in Section A.4.3.2, as proxies for
consumer demand elasticities elsewhere in the OECD. We also constructed estimates of the
U.S. domestic supply elasticity for each product using equation (6') for the supply elasticity from
Section A.4.2.2.5 computed at the mean production level for facilities supplying the product.
The U.S. domestic supply elasticity is similarly used as a proxy for the supply elasticity of other
OECD producing countries.
A-101
-------
The data for transportation costs from the U.S. to foreign ports were derived from a
number of different sources. Transportation costs between Canada and the U.S. for several
different pulp and paper products were provided through personal communication with the
economics staff at the Forest Products Laboratory of the U.S. Forest Service in Madison, WI.6S
These sources also provided expert opinion estimates for transportation costs from the eastern
U.S. to Europe and from the western U.S. to Asia. The latter estimates were verified with data
on transport costs of pulp products from Seattle to Japan provided in. a report published by the
Center for International Trade in Forest Products at the University of Washington.66
A.4.4.1.4 Results. Table A-14 presents the numerically computed import supply and
export demand elasticities for each product. In addition, we report the domestic demand and
supply estimates that were used to construct these estimates, the share of U.S. consumption that
is imported from OECD countries, and the share of U.S. production that is exported to OECD
countries. The foreign trade elasticity estimates were computed as weighted averages of the
bilateral trade elasticities with Canada and multilateral trade elasticities with the rest of the
world. We concentrated on trade with OECD countries because OECD was the only data
source that could provide information on the countries of origin for U.S. imports and countries
of destination for U.S. exports by any meaningful product classifications. The origin and
destination data were needed to compute the international trade elasticities (see import supply
and export demand equations above). Note that the shares reported in Table A-14 were used
for the purpose of computing the international trade elasticities only. The total value and
volume of U.S. imports and exports data by product group, the data used to compute total
production by U.S. producers and total consumption by U.S. consumers for use in the market
model, were derived from API data.685
In regard to providing model parameters, the OECD data for Canada were more
consistent than for other OECD countries so that the foreign trade elasticity for Canada was
used in the model if the Canadian share of U.S. imports or exports for a particular product
Si
5Export data for production category 70, molded pulp, are from the U.S. Department of
Commerce.69
A-102
-------
TABLE A-14
FOREIGN TRADE ELASTICITIES—PULP
AND PAPER PRODUCTS
Domestic
Demand
Product Elasticity
Pulp
1
2
3
4
Paper
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
Paperboard
40
41
-0.750
-0.413
-0.913
-1.051
-0.301
-1.135
-1.839
-0.232
-0.647
-0.647
-1.907
-1.907
-0.574
-1.937
-1.937
-1.937
-1.937
-1.937
-1.937
-1.937
-1.93 7
-0.894
-0.235
-0.353
Domestic
Supply
Elasticity"
0.2009
0.1856
0.2674
0.2320
0.2939
0.3304
1.6530
0.3087
1.2102
0.1192
0.1858
0.9965
0.8156
1.6309
1.2618
N/A
1.6309
2.2533
1.6309
1.2049
1.6586
1.6309
0.3158
0.2757
Import
Supply
Elasticity
11.047
5.964
175.119
20.8 07
1.498
17.255
68.951
6.797
28.2 23
63.408
29.041
119.454
65.95 2
457.782
139.176
130.776
28.297
41.849
—
—
791.116
424.372
5.797
11.590
Export
Demand
Elasticity
-4.377
-5.752
-872.206
-26.652
-43.172
-100.884
-299.428
-41.980
-153.329
-367.272
-141.519
-95.968
-43.445
-84.030
-213.117
-200.201
-47.521
-70.2 55
-3.896
-2.408
-145.232
-81.303
-25.232
-49.011
Import
Share of
Consumption11
0.2037
0.13 79
0.0033
0.2377
0.6146
0.1105
0 .0970
0.1226
0.1060
0.1060
0.1060
0.0789
. 0.0789
0.0065
0.0600
0.0600
0.0670
0:0670
—
—
0.0065
0.006 5
0.1060
0.1060
Export
Share of
Production1"
0.2490
0.1087
0.0005
0.1388
0.0377
0.0166
0.0203
0.0166
0.0179
0.0179
0.0179
0.0952
0.0952
0.0305
0.0304
0.0 304
0.0359
0.0359
—
—
•0.0305
0.0305
0.0179
0.0179
A-103
-------
TABLE A-14 (cont)
Product
42
43
50
51
52
60
61
62
63
64
65
66
70
Domestic
Demand
Elasticity
-0.235
-1.032
-0.940
-0.259
-2.930
-0.752
-0.752
-0.752
-0.752
-0.752
-0.752
-0.75?
-0.752
Domestic
Supply
Elasticity1
0.4928
0.3545
0.8820
N/A
0.7406
1.0139
0.7481
0.4430 .
0.6807
0.6807
0.6807
0.6807
0.2382
Import
Supply
Elasticity
13.088
17.414
14.917
57.453
384.651
611.789
485.303
584.004
584.004
584.004
584.004
212.68
Export
Demand
Elasticity
-57.169
-11.118
—
-7.758
-29.741
-29.630
-47.093
-37.362
-44.956
-44.956
-44.956
-44.956
-36.559
Import
Share of
Consumption1*
0.1060
0.0893
—
0.0893
0.0893
0.0047
0.0034
0.0034
0.0034
0.0034
0.0034
0.0034
0.0065
Export
Share of
Production1*
0.0 179
0.1199
—
0.1199
0.1199
0.0427
0.0323
0.0323
0.0323
0.0323
0.0323
0.0323
0.0305
'Table A-12.
bBased on U.S. imports from and exports to OECD countries as reported in OECD67 for product
groups different from those reported here.
A-104
-------
group exceeded 25 percent. We provide the foreign trade elasticities incorporated into the
model in Table A-15.
Results indicate rather large import supply and export demand elasticities for most
products. In these cases, U.S. imports (exports) are a very small portion of total production and
consumption in the rest of the world and are, for all practical purposes, price-takers on the world
market for these products. The exceptions occur in the categories where foreign trade is a large
component of total U.S. consumption or production. For instance, the U.S. imports over 60
percent of the newsprint it consumes (product 20), and 98 percent of these imports are from
Canada. Canada exports far more newsprint to the U.S. than it consumes internally. Recalling
equation (34), we see that these factors combine to make the import supply elasticity for
newsprint relatively low (1.498). Employing the logic from the preceding argument, the U.S. is
not a small consumer of Canadian production; therefore, changes in U.S. consumption can have
a nontrivial effect on the import price. A similar case is made for U.S. exports of Special Alpha
and dissolving woodpulp (product 1), which constitutes 25 percent of domestic production and
faces a fairly low export demand elasticity of -4.377.
The results here suggest an inverse relationship between the proportional and absolute
effects of a domestic price change on foreign trade. Where foreign trade is a relatively minor
component of U.S. consumption or production, elasticities imply that regulation-induced price
changes may generate large proportional changes in imports and exports. But these changes may
not be so large in absolute value, given the small initial values of foreign trade. On the other
hand, price-taking in world markets should dampen the price effects of regulation in U.S.
markets by suggesting large potential import supplies at the "world" price and the inability to
raise the price of exports on world markets.
s A.4.5 Calibration of the Economic Model
To perform the regulatory market analysis, the model must allow for comparing a
historical equilibrium generated by existing conditions that is assumed to be observable, and a
hypothetical or post-compliance equilibrium that the model produces under a changed policy
A-105
-------
TABLE A-15
FOREIGN TRADE ELASTICITIES USED IN ECONOMIC MODEL
Product
Pulp
1
2
3
4
14
15
Paper
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
Import Supply Elasticity
0.7657"
1.0039"
29.3906"
6.0001"
10b
NA
0.466"
2.012a
6.575"
1.011"
3.688"
1.007"
2.703"
1.389"
0.442"
13.608C
13.608"
NA
5.827"
6.969"
13.608C
13.608C
13.608*
13.608'
Export Demand Elasticity
-4.377
-5.752
-20
-26.652
NA
-10b
-44.557"
-18.5029"
-18.8722"
-9.5657"
-24.7128"
. -6.9822"
-17.1357"
-0.6798"
-0.1954"
-51.1171"
-24.2047"
NA
-24.3361"
-29.1077"
-1.7128"
-1.7128"
-51.5154"
-36.4688"
-------
TABLE A-15 (cont.)
Product
Paperboard
40
41
42
43
50
51
52
60
61
62
63
64
65
66
70
Import Supply Elasticity
1.11'
1.161
1.572"
1.5588a
4.1219d
NA
4.1219"
31.5747"
44.1675"
35.8311"
42.3362"
42.3362"
42.3362"
42.3362"
67.3917"
Export Demand Elasticity
-6.624"
-6.8143"
-9.3803"
-2.356"
-5.5834d
NA
-5.5834"
-29.6295
-9.7706"
-7.9264"
-9.3655"
-9.3655"
-9.3655"
-9.3655"
-14.0005"
"Value equal to that computed for Canada rather than value reported in Table A-14.
bAssumed values, data not available to compute foreign trade elasticities.
"Assumed value to be same as that computed for product 31.
dAssumed value to be same as that computed for product 52.
A-107
-------
regime. The assumption of an "observable" equilibrium leads directly to the need for and
construction of a data set that fulfills the equilibrium conditions in a competitive market model
of the U.S. pulp and paper industry. The base year of analysis is 1989, the latest year for which
facility-level production data are available for all mills included in the National Census. The
baseline data set for this model is a collection of data from the National Census, including data
on facility-level output and production processes, and the other sources noted above in
estimating supply and demand function parameters.'
For the particular functions assumed for supply and demand, we chose parameter values
so that the model will exactly reproduce the 1989 equilibrium values as a solution to the model.
This procedure is commonly referred to in the computable general equilibrium literature as
"calibration." Calibration is augmented by a literature search or econometric estimation for key
parameters. Typically, key parameters are more or less synonomous with elasticities. In this
case, we used the econometric estimates of the key parameters (j8s and elasticities) and assumed
functional forms of the supply and demand relations to calibrate the model. This procedure not
only guarantees that base year market supply equals market demand for all commodities but also
that facility-level supply responses given 1989 market prices are consistent with those observed in
the base year. This section describes the data modifications and procedures used in constructing
the 1989 baseline data set for analyzing the regulatory impact on the U.S. pulp and paper
industry.
A*4,5,l Supply Parameters
On the supply side, we used the key parameters, that is, /3s and import supply elasticities,
and the assumed functional forms of domestic and foreign supply relations to "calibrate" the
model. This guarantees that facility-level supply and import supply responses given 1989 market
prices arc consistent with those observed in the base year. This section describes the data
modifications and procedures employed on the production, or supply, side of the economic
model.
A-108
-------
A.4,5.1.1 Domestic supply. Recall that one of the supply parameters provided by the
econometric estimation of the supply function is the intercept, 7^, which varies across facilities.
This parameter does not influence the facility's production responsiveness to price changes as
does the /3 parameter. Therefore, we used the 7^ parameter to establish production levels from
the supply function (to be employed in the economic model) that are consistent with those
observed in the base year of analysis, 1989.
The supply relationship for a particular product for the base year of 1989 can be
expressed as
1
J89
(36)
where $ is the econometric estimate for that product's supply function. Solving this equation for
the intercept term yields the following equation:
Jj89 =
1
(37)
This equation can be solved for each facility producing product j to arrive at the value of
7jS9 that will ensure that facility, and thus market, quantity supplied is consistent with production
levels observed in 1989. Thus, for each facility, the 1989 market price for product] will elicit a
production response equal to that level observed for 1989. Backsolving for this parameter to
force such a supply response by mills will not bias the results of the model because it has no
bearing on their production responses to changes in market price. The price responsiveness is a
function of the f} parameter or, more intuitively, a function of the facility's implied supply
elasticity for the product.
A.4.5.1.2 Foreign supply. Recall that the model specifies a general formula for the
foreign supply for each market pulp (qj) and paper and paperbpard product (qj): .
A-KW
-------
and
where Bj and B] are positive constants and £j and £• are positive measures of the foreign supply
elasticities for market pulp (k) and paper and paperboard products (i). The product-specific
constants, B[ and B{ were determined through backsolving techniques to establish production
levels from foreign suppliers (to be employed in the economic model) that are consistent with
those observed in 1989 as determined by data obtained for each product from the American
Paper Institute's Statistics of Paper, Paperboard, and Wood Pulp, 1990.™ Thus, B£ and Bj were
adjusted so that each product's foreign supply equation is exact using 1989 data for market prices
and estimates of the foreign supply elasticity.
A-4.5.2 Demand Parameters
On the demand side, we used key parameters (i.e., the purchased input ratios and the1
domestic and foreign demand elasticities) and assumed functional forms of the derived demand
for market pulp and the domestic and foreign demand for paper and paperboard products to
"calibrate" the model. This procedure guarantees that market supply equals market demand for
all commodities given 1989 market prices. This section describes the data modifications and
procedures employed on the consumption, or demand, side of the economic model.
A.4.5.2.I Domestic demand. The calibration technique differs across product type,
specifically market pulp and paper and paperboard products. These data modifications and
procedures are described in the following sections.
A-lUl
-------
A.4.5.2.1.1 Market pulps. Recall that the model does not specify an exogenous demand
function for market pulps because that demand is derived from the paper supply decisions at the
£
integrated and paper mills. Once the paper and paperboard production decisions (#..) at each
mill have been made, the mill-specific purchased input ratios for each market pulp («£) will
determine the domestic demand for each market pulp (qt) as
d y y P s
*k - j i ajik «ji '
The mill-specific purchased input ratios for each market pulp (a£ ) were adjusted to establish
consumption levels by domestic consumers (to be employed in the economic model) so that for
each market pulp
Domestic _ Domestic Foreign _ Foreign
Consumption ~ Production Imports Exports
Domestic production was determined by summing facility-level production data for each market
pulp from the National Census, while foreign imports and exports were determined using data
obtained for each market pulp from the American Paper Institute's Statistics of Paper,
Paperboard, and Wood Pulp.11 The mill-specific purchased input ratios for each market pulp
were adjusted by a factor K across all mills to calibrate the model so that the derived demand for
5
market pulp is exact, given the paper and paperboard production decisions (#..) at each mill,
that is,
y y P s
j i ** ajik qji
satisfies the identity listed above for each market pulp.
A.4.5.2.1.2 Paper and paperboard products. Recall that the model specifies a general
formula for the domestic demand for each paper and paperboard product (q*j), that is,
A-lll
-------
where Aj is a positive constant and 77? is the negative measure of the domestic demand elasticity.
The product-specific demand parameters, A;, were determined through backsolving techniques to
establish consumption levels by domestic consumers (to be employed in the economic model)
that are consistent with the following identity for each marketable product:
Domestic _ Domestic Foreign Foreign
Comsumption Production Imports Exports
Domestic production was determined by summing facility-level production data for each product
from the National Census; foreign imports and exports were determined using data obtained for
each product from the American Paper Institute's Statistics of Paper, Paperboard, and Wood
Pulp.12 Thus, the A,- parameters were used to calibrate the model so that each product's •
domestic demand equation satisfies the identity listed' above for each paper and paperboard
product using 1989 data for market prices and estimates of the domestic demand elasticity.
A.4.52,2 Foreign demand. Recall that the model also specifies a general formula for the
foreign demand tfor each market pulp (qjj) and paper and paperboard product (q*), that is
and
where AJ and A* arc positive constants and r?J and rfi, the foreign demand elasticities for market
pulp (k) and paper anci paperboard products (i), are negative. The product-specific foreign
demand parameters, AJ and A?, were determined through backsolving techniques to establish
consumption levels by foreign consumers (to be employed in the economic model) that are
consistent with those observed in 1989 as determined by data obtained for each product from the
American Paper Institute's Statistics of Paper, Paperboard, and Wood Pulp.13 Thus, AJ and A;
A-112
-------
were used to calibrate the model so that each product's foreign demand equation is exact using
1989 data for market prices and estimates of the foreign demand elasticity.
A.4.6 Model Baseline Values
This section presents the 1989 baseline data set for analyzing the regulatory impact on
the U.S. pulp and paper industry.
A.4.6.1 Market Prices and Output
Table A-16 shows the 1989 equilibrium prices, domestic production, exports, and imports
i
of each market pulp, paper, and paperboard product. These values represent the starting point
for imposing the regulations and assessing the impacts. Prices for market pulp, paper, and
paperboard products were imputed using data on value'of product shipments and quantity of
product shipped obtained from the U.S. Department of Commerce's Current Industrial Reports:
Pulp, Paper, and Board™ Domestic production data for market pulp, paper, and paperboard
products were derived from facility-level production data for 1989 from EPA's 1990 National
Census of Pulp, Paper, and Paperboard Manufacturing Facilities.15 For export and import
quantities, we used data published by the American Paper Institute in Statistics of Paper,
Paperboard, and Wood Pulp.1''
We computed aggregate prices lor the three major product groupings: market pulp,
paper products, and paperboard products. Each aggregate price is a 1989 market quantity
weighted average of the market prices for all products within the major group. The weights used
to compute the,pre-compliance price level were also used to compute the post-compliance price
level, akin to a Laspeyres price index. Key commodities within the market pulp group include
bleached sulfitc (79 percent of market pulp traded in 1989) and Special Alpha and dissolving
woodpulp (12 percent). For the paper product group, uncoated free sheet accounts for 24
percent of paper marketed in 1989 followed closely by clay-coated printing paper (22 percent),
newsprint (16 percent), and tissue (14 percent). For the paperboard product group, unbleached
A-113
-------
OS
OO
O\
cn
W
D
>
U
g
w
CA
S
• •
H
OS
Q
i
CU
Ctf
u
c-
Cu
I
Ss
** t!
1
I
1
1 "^
**"''
a
3
a
c
•- 'Ji
w £
«i C
s i
O "J
°l
tn
V 9
•O B.
S E
H ~'
.1
fli WS
1 1
LT-. JP
^* CL
x
id
y C
ts .2
« «
i 3
O o
fi S
cu
t
||
cu 5?
51
VO
vo"
,_,
S
o"
I— <
o
o
10"
CN
VO
s-
ON
CO
o
•n
CO
VO
<*,
<0
1—4
OO
T— (
ON
oo
CN
VO
CO
oo
c
rj-
^4"
CO
CO
in
CO
feo
JC.
c.
t3
Sr^ t~
O i-l
ON^ -nr r-
T— (
CO VO CN
CN^ CN CO
ocf
co r~ oo
V~t CO IT)
r-^ co
co
t> OC CN
vq^ t-i co
r- o ON
CN CO CO
ON p^ p^
^^ rO C^*
VC rr vo
VC ro w>
oo
oo
TO
g
cs
vo
VO
VO
CN
CO
co co
T-H O OO
en ^* co
O\ CO OO
ON" ,-T
CN ON
VO i—i
r~ CN
ON i-T
CO
CO
CN
oo
CN
CO
co
SI
CN
oo
CO
co
o
CN
oo
ON
CO
vo oo
S
CO
oo
oo
ON CN
VO CN
ON
in
t- 1-1
ON
CO ^f TJ-
i-" OO »-«
•* vC
Tt 1-1
TT
CO
TT
OO
O
CN"
ON ij
O I-H
s si
vo
l-H CO
ON" r-T
OO
t--
in
ON vo
CO CN
CS 1-1
O
CO
CO I-H
S1 "-1
ON co
CN" I-H"
CO
R
ON
•n
CO
«•«» &»> to &* v=> &$ v*
ON
C3
CO
CO
oo
V)
o co o
C3 CO ON
O OO P^
TT •<*• T-H
o in r~
CN
««
v*
•o
£
a,
i
^-
SD
"c
v:
u-
J3
IS
1
a
o
d.
s.
OX)
u
s.
n
•5
T-' CN CO -^f- «O VO
CN CN CN CN CN CN
CN
A-114
-------
fi
1
vo
*•*
1
•<5
U
as
L_
fc^
"SS —
•8 a
3*
^
i
o
£
^w^
V3
*rf
^5
e
O*
S
u .S
'"i a*
e E
& s
° e
r
V 0
1 t
.S,
^*
,O e
FT-J 3J
^^ CM
1
.a i
8*1
g .3
* S
0-
^
•- 1
J™ g?-
|
u
S
•o
£
Cu
cooNin^T— icoovo
T-H in ON ^~ vo o\ r^ vo
in T-H f-4 cs
«n"
rNjo-^-^CSrtT-jt^
ON in in >^ m oo vo 10
rf T-I Z 0)
w-T
T-HCScs^cscsoio)
'^H ^--i
»-iO\(S^!oNONONON
tS -<3- g?
CM t^ CO ^ OO T-H f^ ^
ON in ON *^~ in ON vo vo
«n"
^ocor-ooo^S
• r*- co » — ' co *^ • "
^\ovdo6r~coI2S
,_ (T-iinco^ootsifNi
«oovo r~t-- t^ ,_;•,_;•
*^ ** **
a s §
!^ *»f W
"5 3 *-
^ "s C
1 s ^ 5
1 1 1. 1
BO .*: j«:
iS -p 8 M •*
is C. « « ~>
OB ** .£• ei efl S
e w> ^= x S ""•
•= c <« — — eo
o &• -s u. i- i- c u.
3 R cl ^ ^ Ji'x °
• P ^ w 606 ^ 6
oo c — rt ro T m vc
CN CO co CO CO ro CO CO
T-H
VO
T-H
CS
ON
T-H
r-
T— t
O
i
^••4
^H
Specialty packaging
CO
f-
ON
ON
OO
CM
CM
ON
£
p
So
T~^
«y»
C
w
j=
«j
rt
<4-T
Glassine.greaseproo
8
S
T-H"
rf
f-»r
CO
CO
c-»
^^
OO
CO"
ON
cT
"^
VO
co
rt
rboard Products
^J
1"
s
ON"
T-H
s
f^«.
T-H
in
VO
^Q
VO
•"(^
CM"
r-
CO
ON"
vH
!n
ON
CO
"H
rt
O
•e
Q.
D.
U>
1
1
CO ^
f^i l^?"
X— 4
VO ^~
VO Z.
in m
OO CO
CN" S
ON co
CO CO
Construction paper
Hardboard(a)
in In
A-115
-------
4)
•O
SJD
E s
o »
a
ve>
ca
.Si o
Q
U
VO
vo"
cn
vo
oo r- r-
OO O i-H
en -3- CM
CM" -r
8
en oo
i-< 00
CM VO
CM"
VO
VO
>n
m
00 en CM
oo
CM
CM
in
VO
3
a
s o
T—I
in"
(S
OO
ir
cs
^
ON
in in
ON O
en CM
CM" r-T
O
CN (N
CM en
CN
CM
en
06
en
CM
CM
>n CM
O en
vo >n
oo CM
vo vo
CM
VO
c- i: £
c 5
ft t- C
"*J m *-
-O ^ _X Z-
.2 P
o, ^
CM
o «—
CM
vc
VO
vo
A-116
-------
kraft packaging board accounts for 43 percent of paperboard traded in 1989 with recycled
paperboard and serai-chemical paperboard accounting for 19 and 12 percent, respectively.
The pulp, paper, and paperboard product groups defined in the National Census match
product definitions put forth by the U.S. Department of Commerce's Current Industrial Reports
but do not exactly match API's import and export categories. Subappendix Table AA-2
summarizes the system we used to cross-reference pulp and paper product categories between
the National Census, the Current Industial Reports, and API's import and export categories.
A.4.6.2 Foreign Trade
Table A-17 provides the 1989 baseline values of shipments and quantities for all exported
and imported products included in the economic model. These values represent the starting
values on which we impose the regulations and assess the impacts on international trade.
AA.63 Facilities, Product Lines, and Output
Table A-18 provides the 1989 baseline values for the number of facilities and product
lines included in the analysis, as well as industry output by major product group. These baseline
values arc further broken down by the type of facility: nonintegrated (pulp or paper only) and
integrated. These values represent the starting values with which to assess the production and
closure, impacts.
A.4.6.4 Revenue, Production Cost, and Profit Impacts
Table A-19 provides the 1989 baseline values of industry revenue, cost, and profit
separated by type of facility. These values represent the starting values with which to assess the
revenue, production cost, and profit impacts.
A-117
-------
0\
CO
o\
.2
n
Si
I
e o
Ed
W
on
w
W
03
I*
B O
OJ
hi
*
s e
1
S §
CO ON
•^
VO
VO
0
Tf
CS
CS
£
CO
vo"
CO
S
g
co
co oo
CO TH
x_' VO
**3" ON oo
^sl" CS ON
T-^ t\ OO^
i-? vrf cs"
ON OO rj-
•vt- OO OO
VO" CO" ^
O O\ VO
CS CS i-*
•^ o\ es
o r- T-T
OO
CO
oo
•
8
co1"
OO VO
vo
CO O\
a\
Si
*.
i
8-^1-
oo
10
co
co
oo
oo oo
10 -r-i
CO VO
O 1-H
CO
*-H >O O
oo^ 10 co
r-T ocf i-T
VO
vo
>0
CO
CO
CO
co
o\ i-.
oo
VO
cs vo
VO CO
o oo
vo"
oo —.
c~- oo
VO *-<
oo
VO
cs
CO
vo
~ ~ 3 *>
CD «-i j-i IO OO
•^- o\ cs oo
CO VO
•a f:
« w> jc g
fl I 1
o .«
§• -B "a
.S2 o
S O
73 _ z:
. C 3 =1
CS CO CO
C/J CO
g-8
b-S
CO rt
1
•o
o
•o o
u g
£
oo
cs
CM
CO
"1.
co"
VO
VO
CO
o
T3 «fc
60 S
-
Du. ro ;-; u. tZT
60 C. U C. D
«
»— CS CO
«-• cj; cs
cs
CS
cs
A-118
-------
.-^
1
1
J
OS
^
8
e
Jl
a
«
V
•o
2
^""
VI
t
^
&.
js
r
5.
X
U
^
a ***
*3^
^ '""'
s-'
y*^
•^4?
'a o
« **
s *fe
«£
o
>• *^
ȣ
"S 0
li
v~>'
ii
s"^1
«"^
S 5
Produce Code
s-^
en
en
cT
T— 1
f^
»— 1
^^^
oT
9>
ON
en
r~
Bleached
_ bristols
rr
"^ en" vo
VO O VO
cs v~> '"I
T-T ^^ (S
en T-I en
T— t
^N^^
jj^ oT" ON
w-> o T-"
IO CN^
"^ ^
oo t~- r~
O r-t O
TT^ • CS_ VO^
T-I en T- <
~ ~
vo ON vo
ON en fS
•* •* 01
2 r~ oo
Svb" 06"
«— ' *r
•—i O *^*
TT en rr
^" *"J*
w £. *~
.c re O
T^ ' . CS
r— (
8^""* f* ON
en
T"^
CM^ ON^ «r^
en
fS
r*^ ^D rO
«— • O "T
P. •*! ^i
en C** r*^
{N «N
— ON (N
rt - t^- t-
•y
*~*
C ^-> CJ g; ,^,
"?» -O S O o
& c -^ w O
"^ 3 OZ) *5
1 IS ^.2 £>
5 . 5 S B o & •§
-c *T^ -c "Si^ — c. S
*^ w «_* 5^ •— • •-* ^r ^*
Oca r^ 5 "•3 o ^ -^
on ^ Jp v; U/ C- -•>
C*J f*^ ^ tO
ro CO rO r*"i
A-119
-------
I
O1
*•*
I
*
***•
W
J
ea
e
•o
2
H
Wl
r
o
n.
J
V)
~
a
a.
X
rX4
^^
MM fT^
i> fe
•S *&
C o
es *-
-^
V ^^
If
*B
"S 0
S3 ••••
3 <^
Qr ^
II
>*^ <^
S"">
/-N
>^. ^
^s* 5*"»
•M* C
C 0
s «-
3 -i
CD'S
Produce Code
ON
T— <
l^i
oo
-
T-H
s
cs"
cs
ON
cT
ON
«_•
O
CO
•n P
VO^ 5o
c-^ t-^
T-l
t~ CO
oo r~
r2 {^
cs" oT
cs
•* . o
oo vo
CO OO
o" ^ •
r-« i—l
ON O\
C,
SJ "
V. C
Specialty
packaging
Glassinc.grca
roof,parchmc
t~- 00 ,
CO CO
^ SN
^T °^
S3 g
•- O\
r— (
^" OO
vo ON
O CS
co" cs"
VO OO
O <->
°l ^
vo" in"
CS vo
CO
co in
-<3- \c
CS 0
oC 3
^ s:
S £
r- to
C^ vO
OC -T
co CN
^
wrboard Product
Unbl kraft
packaging
paperboard
cC ^?
(o~ o
in vo
TJ- >n^
r— < . C***
r^ o
oo cs
r— 1 T— 1
CS O
t-^ o
cs" co"
"^" VO
oo in
.-i vo
i — 1 r— 1
in i-i
vC vo
'H *°
r-T o"
*-* r-
— i m
CO 00
r— t
Scmichcmicnl
paperboard
Recycled
paperboard
i- ' CS
rr TJ-,
vo 6^
^* i ,
T—* r-H
VO
cs G^
•n
—
T— i -
,^\
Hardboard?
in
o
V,
CS
in
A-120
-------
i
PQ
•o
2
H
S O
« •"
S ^i
oo
0\
vo
e
o
O
a.
s 3
3 «
a.
it
C O
« •*••
3 -2^
02
en
oo
(N
e
U
I
•o
E
a.
o
•e
u
g
en
r— 1
OO
i— 1
S
oo
CO
T— <
O
00
en
5
o
OS T3
O >-
60 0
^Q
2 o
vc
P-s*. ^" N. ^*V
r- ^ go ON en
°X en' cs *° °°
c— ^ ^06" oT
en
£ CS CS S S
o oo in r— ••*•
TT O en ON oo
t~~ in en in vo
06" 06" 06" r~~ 06"
CM tS tN CO Cn
VO
od"
S
rf
vo
CO
en"
CO
ON
ON
^H
^f
en
c.
C/3
« S
S-o
o o
«^" >—
^ Q.
O
•a
o
3
•a
2
a.
^]
1
oo
P
o
c
rt
•4-J
c/:
'o
£
•§
3
0
3
C
K!
•o
rt *-<
||
i o
i— i
).-* &•
Pi
<£ -
O •"
3 l=
C S
c3^
CC 0
C T3
c c
"ii ^
^ o
J2
^_( UM
£ "2
— o
"*- 0
c^ 3
ic C.
A-121
-------
00
**£
3
»
<
E-
o\
CO
W
P
|
W
3
w
CO
CO
§
a,
S
O
a
z
^"
z
rj
P
D
§
ft,
c/T
w
E
u
(£.
O
Z
cu
O
^•x
J>"»
CO
I
§,
Q.
3
O
"O
1- CO
rt t>
1-1 *a
o o
rv C
03 P-(
(L,
tn
^^
u- O
O 3
CUTS
CC O
•^ «a
Ok
CO
"3 -a
PH g
0-,
M
C 0 „
•s J «
2 "a c
O g "j
J?"^1
.S.2
2:1
t) 0
CM CQ
o ^
OO
od"
r-
o
od"
g
^
rj-
CO
CO
en
"§
•a
(•*
£,
co
_c
'c
c
Z
O 1/1
od"
t--
0 S
od"
9
? 0
•n [^
^ P)
oo g
™ %
•H
CS
u*
c.
c.
c/i "O
Z« C!
"E "
.£" c-
3 ^
OL, d.
CO
S
cs
CO
o
cs"
CO
§
vT
oo
CO
CN
_c/j
j^;
""
-a
u
E
^
*•»
—
r~
s
r-
o"
1
i— r
T— 1
oo
VO
VC
in
1"
•a
c
•""
7^7
— r
V*
^*>
H
M22
-------
2
^j.
u
ea
^
o\
3
i-rt
c/f
u
<
*^
Ed
g
td
Cfl
ca
c/3
C/3
O
O
z
^
Cfl
W
z
u
^
Ed
as
T
yy^
>.
•i
O
fc.
£ ^_^
W) '"'
2 tS
O
-
J ^
«~
5 *
^e
/£.
>>
1
N~'
s
4)
V
OS
2
5
V
_. WD
• MM ^
^l
O
H
V
_ W5
j= «
^
o
H
— wo
11
^1
_
s
"o
4)
a.
^
j«2
•^
r:
(x
>r> oo cs
vo ^ r^i
ON *o •rr
Tt" ^-T erf
O\ CN *O
t— i oo ^
vO r~ ON
O >o ^1"
m" rf o
T-H r-H
rt § VO
r~- w>
-------
A.4.6J) Employment
As shown i'n Table A-20, total employment at nonintegrated and integrated mills included
in the economic model is 217,625. This figure includes both production and nonproduction
workers as reported in the National Census. The 1992 Lockwood-Post's Directory reports total
employment in 1989 at pulp, paper, and board mills as 245,600.77 The difference may be
attributed to the exclusion of "other" production employees reported in the National Census.
A number of mills included in the model lacked employment data from the National
Census. Thus, we imputed employment data for these mills by multiplying baseline output by the
average employee to output ratio for similar type mills (i.e., pulp, paper, and integrated). This
method was done separately for production workers .and total workers with nonproduction
workers being the difference. The ratios for pulp mills were 0.00167 for production workers and
0.00192 for total workers. The ratios for production and total workers were 0.0049 and 0.00669
for paper mills and 0.00419 and 0.00554 for integrated mills.
A.4.7 Market Equilibria
This section explains the major components of the model. A complete list of exogenous
and endogenous variables, as well as the model equations, is given in Table A-21.
The market supply of pulp (Q\) is the sum of supply from all market pulp producers, that
is,
S I
where qj is foreign supply of market pulp (k) and ? q* is the domestic supply of market pulp
(k), which is the sum of market pulp (k) production across all U.S. mills (j). In similar fashion,
A-124
-------
TABLE A-20
FACILITY-LEVEL EMPLOYMENT: BASELINE VALUES, 1989
Employment
Facility Type
Nonintegrated mills
Pulp mills
Paper and paperboard
mills
Integrated mills
Total, all industry
Production
51,738
7,386
44,352
119,221
170,959
Nonproduction
14,840
1,340
13,499
31,827
46,666
Total
66,578
8,727
57,851
151,047
217,625
A-125
-------
TABLE A-21
PULP AND PAPER MODEL SUMMARY
Variables
Description
Exogenous
•nl
Tji
M M
J7J
A?, Af, AJ
Demand elasticity for domestic consumers of U.S. paper and
paperboard products i=l to 31.
Demand elasticity for foreign consumers of U.S. paper and
paperboard products i=l to 31 (exports).
Demand elasticity for foreign consumers of U.S. market pulps k=l to
6 (exports).
Import supply elasticity of foreign paper and paperboard products
i=l to 31.
Import supply elasticity of foreign pulp products k=l to 6.
Supply function parameters for paper and paperboard products (i)by
mill 0)-
Supply function parameters for market pulps (k) by mill (j).
Production capacity for paper and paperboard products (i) and
market pulps (k) manufactured at each mill (j).
Minimum economically feasible production level for paper and
paperboard products (i) and market pulps (k) manufactured at each
mill 0).
Cost indices of variable-proportion inputs into paper and paperboard
(i) and pulp (k) production by mill (j).
Input ratios for pulps manufactured on-site (o) and purchased from
the market (p). Indicates the amount of pulp k required to produce
paper and paperboard product i at mill j.
Regulatory control costs (per unit of output) for pulps (k) by mill (j).
Demand function parameters for paper and paperboard products (i)
and exported market pulps (k). (Multiplicative constants for domestic
(d) and foreign (x) demand.)
Import supply function parameters for those paper and paperboard
products and market pulps produced abroad and shipped to U.S.
(Multiplicative constants for paper and paperboard (i) and market
pulp (k) supply.)
A-126
-------
TABLE A-21 (cont)
Variables
Description
Endogenous
Pi
q?, <& Q?
qt q* Q S
Price of paper and paperboard products.
Price of market pulps.
Domestic (mill-level) and foreign supply ( q ^ , q?), of paper and
paperboard products and market-level supply (Qf).
Domestic (mill-level) and foreign supply ( q^k , q£) of market
pulps and market-level supply (Q£).
Domestic and foreign demand (qf, q?) for paper and paperboard
products and market-level demand (Q^).
Domestic and foreign demand (qj|, q£) for market pulps and market-
level demand (Q°).
Equations
Market Supply of Paper and Paperboard Products:
of - £
where
and
2-t q. =
J
yj
- BIW
i + — i I— 11 2
f\
without regulation
A-127
-------
TABLE A-21 (cent)
Variables Description
or
k=l
Market Supply of Pulp Products:
where
and
v/ith
regulation
wit/iout regulation
or
with regulation
Market Demand of Paper and Paperboard Products:
0? • 9? * «f
where
gf - 4 [PlJ"
A-128
-------
TABLE A-21 (conL)
Variables Description
and
± • 4 N"
Market Demand for Pulp Products:
where
and
A-129
-------
the market supply of paper and paperboard products (Qf) is the sum of supply from all paper
and paperboard producers, that is,
where q- is foreign supply of paper and paperboard products (i) and V q.., is the domestic
J JIK
supply of paper and paperboard products (i), which is the sum of paper and paperboard (i)
production across all U.S. mills (j).
The market demand for pulp (Q°) is the sum of demand from all market pulp
consumers, that h,
0° = a* + ad
j£ J,- •*&' •* If
where qj is foreign demand for market pulp (k) and q£ is the domestic demand for market pulp
(k), which is the sum of the derived demand for market pulp (k) across all U.S. mills (j)., In
similar fashion, the market demand of paper and paperboard products (Qf) is the sum of
demand from all paper and paperboard consumers, that is,
nP x d
27 = qi + qL
where q* is foreign demand of paper and paperboard products (i) and q? is the domestic demand
of paper and paperboard products (i).
Each type of facility, integrated or nonintegrated, has a different decision to make.
Integrated mills must determine optimal output given the market prices for all paper products
they produce, which will determine the amount of internal pulp to produce. An excess supply of
pulp will spillover into the market, while an excess demand will cause the facility to demand
market pulp. For nonintegrated paper mills, the optimal level of output will be determined by
the market prices for pulp inputs and final paper and paperboard outputs the optimal level of
A-130
-------
output will determine the corresponding araojunt market pulp to purchase. For pulp mills, the
optimal supply of market pulp will be detertnined by the price of market pulp.
Facility responses and market adjustments can be conceptualized as an interactive
feedback process. Facilities face increased production costs due to compliance, which cause
facility-specific production responses. The cumulative effect of these responses leads to a change
in the market price that all producers (affected and unaffected) and consumers face, which leads
to further responses by producers (affected and unaffected) as well as consumers and thus new
ri*
market prices, and so'on. The new post-regulatory equilibria is the result of a series of iterations
between producer and consumer responses and market adjustments until a stable market price
arises where total market supply equals total market demand, that is,
and
Q • = Q • > for au paper and paperboard products (i)
S D
Q, = q , , for all market pulps (i)
(42)
(43)
This process is simulated given the producer and consumer response functions and market
adjustment mechanisms to arrive at the post-compliance equilibria.
The process for determining equilibrium prices (and outputs) is modeled as a Walrasian
auctioneer. The auctioneer calls out a price for each product and evaluates the reactions by all
participants (producers and consumers, both foreign and domestic), comparing quantities
supplied and demanded to determine the next price that will guide the market closer to
equilibrium (i.e.. market supply equal to market demand). We developed an algorithm to
simulate the auctioneer process and tind a new equilibrium price and quantity for all 37 pulp and
paper product markets simultaneously. Decision rules were established to ensure that the
process will converge to an equilibrium and to specify the conditions for equilibrium. The result
of this approach is a vector of post-compliance product prices that equilibrates supply and
demand for all product markets. To capture the derived demand nature of the market for
market pulps, this auctioneer algorithm was applied simultaneously to both the markets for final
paper and paperboard products and market pulps.
A-131
-------
The algqrithm for deriving the post-compliance equilibria in all markets can be
generalized to five recursive steps:
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
Impose the control costs on the mills, thereby affecting their supply decisions.
Recalculate the market supply of each paper and paperboard product and each market
pulp product. The new market supply of each product will determine the demand for
pulp in a derived manner through the input ratios. Therefore, demand for market pulp is
simultaneously determined with paper and paperboard supply.
i
Determine the new prices via the price revision rule for all product markets (i.e., 31
paper and paperboard products and 6 market pulp products).
Recalculate the supply functions for all mills with the new prices, resulting in a new
market supply of paper, paperboard, and market pulp, in addition to derived (domestic)
demand for market pulp. Evaluate domestic demand for paper and paperboard products,
as well as import supply and export demand for' paper, paperboard, and market pulp
products given the new prices.
Return to Step 3, and continue to repeat until equilibrium conditions are satisfied in all
markets (i.e., the ratio of supply to demand is arbitrarily close to one for each and every
product).
A.4.8 Post-Regulatory Impact Estimates
The model results can be summarized as market-level and facility-level impacts due to the
regulations.
A.4.8.1 Market-Level Results
Market-level impacts include the market-level adjustments in price and quantity for all
affected products as well as the changes in international trade flows. In addition, the market
adjustments in price and quantity were used to calculate the changes in the aggregate economic
welfare using applied welfare economics principles. The following sections outline the results
and the methods used to quantify these market-level impacts.
A-132
-------
A.4.8.1.1 Price and quantity impacts. Market adjustments are a result of moving from the
pre-compliance to post-compliance equilibrium. Given the regulatory control costs, the
interaction of facility-level responses and price revision mechanism, modeled as a Walrasian
auctioneer, along with the simultaneous coordination of the final product and input markets
results in a new post-compliance equilibrium with new prices and quantities for all 37 product
markets.
A.4.8.1.2 Foreign trade impacts. The impacts of the regulations on foreign trade in the
pulp and paper industry were estimated by comparing baseline and post-compliance levels of
exports and imports of affected products.
A.4.8.1.3 Economic welfare impacts. The value of environmental improvements that result
from regulatory policy can be measured against the change in economic welfare the policy
generates. Welfare impacts resulting from the regulatory controls on the pulp and paper industry
will extend to the many consumers and producers of pulp and paper products. Consumers of
pulp and paper products will experience welfare impacts due to the adjustments in price and
output of the pulp and paper products caused by imposing the regulations. Producer welfare
impacts result from the changes in product revenues associated with the additional costs of
production and the corresponding market adjustments. The theoretical approach used in applied
welfare economics to evaluate policies follows and indicates the approach used in this study to
estimate changes in economic welfare.
The economic welfare implications of the post-compliance market price and output
changes of pulp and paper products can be examined using two slightly different measures, each
giving a somewhat different insight but the same implications: changes in the net benefits of
consumers and producers based on the price changes, and changes in the total benefits and costs
of pulp and paper products based on the quantity changes. For this analysis, we focused on the
first measure—the changes in the net benefits of consumers and producers. Figures A-23
through A-25 depict the changes in economic welfare by first measuring the change in consumer
A-133
-------
$/Qx
Px2
Px1
$/Qy
P/2
Qx2 Qx1
(a) Market for Paper or Paperboard Product, Qx
Qx/t
Qy2 Qy1
(b) Market for Pulp, Qy
Qy/t
Figure A-23 Change in consumer surplus with regulation
A-134
-------
$/Qx
Px2
Px1
Dx
$/Qy
Py2
Py1
Qx2 Qx1
(a) Market for Paper or Paperboard Product, Qx
Qx/t
Dy
Qy2 Qy1
(b) Market for Pulp, Qy
Qy/t
Figure A-24 Change in producer surplus with regulation
A-135
-------
$/Q>
Px2
Px1
$/Qy
Qx2 Qx1 Qx/t
(a) Market for Paper or Paperboard Product, Qx
Dy
Qy2 Qy1
(b) Market for Pulp, Qy
Qy/t
Figure A-25 Change in economic welfare with regulation
A-136
-------
surplus and then the change in producer surplus. In essence, the demand and supply curves
*»
previously used as predictive devices are now being used as a valuation tool.
This method of estimating the post-regulatory change in economic welfare divides society
into consumers and producers. In a market environment, consumers and producers of the good
or service derive welfare from a market transaction. The difference between the maximum price
consumers are willing to pay for a good and the price they actually pay is referred to as
consumer surplus. Consumer surplus is measured as the area under the demand curve and
above the price of the product. Similarly, the difference between the minimum price producers
are willing to accept for a good and the price they actually receive is referred to as producer
surplus. Producer surplus is measured as the area above the supply curve to the price of the
product. These areas may be thought of as consumers' net benefits of consumption and
producers' net benefits of production, respectively.
In Figure A-23, baseline equilibrium occurs at the intersection of the pulp and paper
product demand curves, Dx and Dy, and supply curves, Sx and Sy. Paper price is Pxl with quantity
Qj,, while pulp price is Py, with quantity Qyl. The increased cost of production with the
regulations will cause the market supply curve of both to shift upward to S^ and Sy, respectively.
The new equilibrium price of paper is P,-, and price of pulp is P^. Higher pulp and paper
product prices mean less consumer welfare, all else being unchanged. In Figure A-23, for both
products, area A represents the dollar value of the annual net loss in consumers' benefits with
the increased price of pulp and paper products. The rectangular portion represents the loss in
consumer surplus on the quantity still consumed, Q^ for paper and Qy2 for pulp, respectively,
while the triangular area represents the foregone surplus resulting from the reduced amount of
pulp and paper product consumed. Q,,- Q,: and Qyl - Qy2, respectively.
Because this analysis involves u derived demand market for pulp, which is not a final
product market, the change in "consumer surplus" shown is actually the sum of the downstream
markets* changes in producer surplus at paper mills and integrated paper producers as well as
the change in consumer surplus for households (sec Just, Heuth, and Schmidt78). Thus, to avoid
double counting, we excluded the consumer surplus measures calculated from the pulp market
A-137
-------
adjustments that are included in the producer surplus changes for paper producers. In addition
to the changes in consumer welfare, producers' welfare also changes with the regulations.
With the increases in pulp and paper product prices, producers receive higher revenues
on the quantity still purchased, Q^ for paper and Q^ for pulp. In Figure A-24, for both
products, area B represents the increase in revenues due to this increase in prices. For each
product, the difference in the areas under the two supply curves up to the original market price,
area C, measures the loss in producers' surplus, which includes the loss associated with the
quantity no longer produced. The net change in producers' welfare is calculated as area B - C.
The change in economic welfare attributable to the compliance costs of the regulations is
the sum of consumer and producer surplus changes. 'The change is - (A) + (B - C) for paper
products, but as mentioned earlier we included only the producer surplus change (B - C) for
market pulp products. The consumer surplus change resulting from the markets for pulp is
included in the producer's surplus change for paper and paperboard products. Figure A-25
shows the net (negative) change in economic welfare associated with the regulations as the sum
of area D for p^per-products and area (B - C), the producer surplus change for pulp products.
This value is the same as the one found by the alternative method of comparing the changes in
the total benefits of consumption and the total costs of production. However, this analysis does
not include the benefits that occur outside the pulp and paper products markets—the value of
the reduced levels of air and water pollution with the regulations. Inclusion of this benefit may
reduce the net cost of the regulations or even make them positive.
A.4.83 Facility-Level Results
Facility-level impacts include an evaluation of the post-regulatory compliance cost;'
product-line and facility closures; and changes in production, production costs, and EBIDT. In
addition, we computed the change in employment attributable to the changes in output at each
mill. These output changes are caused by product-line and facility closures as well as
adjustments in production at mills that continue to operate under regulation. Workers'
dislocation costs associated with industry-wide job losses are also calculated.
A-138
-------
A.4.8.2.1 Post-policy compliance cost. For each regulatory alternative, the post-regulatory
compliance cost at an affected facility has two components:
• Variable compliance cost (i.e., O&M expenditures)
• Fixed compliance cost (i.e., annualized capital expenditures)
The variable compliance cost at each facility depends on its post-compliance output rate, while
the fixed compliance cost, as the name implies, is a constant lump-sum incurred at the facility.
As shown in Figure A-26, the marginal cost curve for the single-product facility shifts upward
from MC to MQ by the per-unit output variable compliance cost (c). The facility response to
the upward shift and new market price (p*1) is to reduce output from q* to q*1. The
corresponding total variable compliance cost at the facility can be calculated as the product of
the per-unit output variable compliance cost (c) and the new output rate (q*1). This cost is
represented by the area A in Figure A-26. This calculation can be extended to the multi-product
facility where total variable costs can be summed across all product-lines that continue operating
after post-regulatory market adjustments.
At the industry-level, the post-policy compliance cost is the sum of the variable and fixed
compliance costs across all facilities and product-lines continuing to operate in the post-
compliance equilibrium. Thus, the post-compliance cost is not necessarily equal to the estimated
compliance costs before accounting for market adjustments. These cost estimates differ because
facilities and product-lines close, and firms decide not to bear the costs of compliance (variable
or fixed). Output rates change at affected facilities so that total variable compliance cost equals
per-unit output variable compliance cost (c) times the post-compliance output rate (q*1) as
opposed to the pre-compliance output rate (q*).
A.4.82.2 Production and closure impacts. The economic model accommodates both
product-line and facility closures in moving from the pre-compliance to post-compliance
equilibrium. Within a model iteration, recalculating market prices allows for the possibility that
the minimum efficient level of production (qm) becomes binding for a product line. In other
A-139
-------
Figure A-26 Variable post-compliance costs
A-140
-------
words the estimated production response to the new prices and costs may drive production levels
below qm. In such a case, the mdtlel "closes" that product line for that facility by setting
production to zero, and market quantities are adjusted accordingly. The same is true when the
entire facility closes because total revenues are less than total avoidable costs. In the case of a
facility closure, the algorithm sets the production for each and every product line at the facility to
zero.
A.4.8.2.3 Revenue, production cost, and profit impacts. The economic model generates
information on the change in facility and market quantities and market prices. This information
is used to compute the change in total revenue and total cost at the facility level. The change in
facility production and market prices effects a change in product revenue at the facility, which is
the difference between pre-compliance product revenue (R(q)) and post-compliance product
revenue (R(q)'):
(44)
In addition, the change in facility production effects a change in production costs, which can be
added to post-compliance costs to estimate the change in total costs for the facility.
As shown in Figure A-27 (a), the variable production costs at the single-product facility
without regulation is the area under the marginal cost curve (MC) up to the current output rate,
q* (as represented by the area A). After imposing the variable control costs, as illustrated in
Figure A-27 (b), the marginal cost curve shifts upward to MC and market price increases to p*'
resulting in a reduced output rate of q*'. The post-compliance total variable production cost at
the facility is represented by the area A' in Figure A-27 (b). The major components are the area
under the original marginal cost curve (MC) up to the new output rate and the area between the
original and new marginal cost curves up to the new output rate—the variable compliance cost.
In addition, the facility no longer incurs the production costs associated with the forgone output
(q* - q*1), represented by the area B in Figure A-27 (b). Thus, the total change in production
cost at the facility can be calculated as the post-compliance variable costs of production minus
A-141
-------
qm q*
a) Total Variable Cost at Facility Without Regulation
b) Total Variable Cost at Facility With Regulation
Figure A-27 Production cost changes due to regulation
A-142
-------
the pre-compliance variable costs of production, which will account for the increase in costs due
to the regulation, and the decrease in costs due to the lower output rate.
The changes in total revenue and total cost were then used to measure the profitability
impact of the regulations at the facility level and at the industry level.
A.4.8.2.4 Employment impacts. The regulatory alternative will displace workers from jobs
by affecting production levels. The methodology employed to estimate the number of displaced
workers depends on the methodology used to project output effects. In this case, changes in
employment at mills that continue to operate after the regulation were estimated by multiplying
a mill-specific ratio of production workers per output (Ej) by the projected change in mill output
= E *
If the mill ceases to operate, then the change in employment at the mill equals total
employment, both production and nonproduction. Thus, the estimate of the change in
employment for the entire industry was obtained by adding the sum of the employment changes
across all mills that continue to operate and the sum of total employment across all mills that
close C:
e.
(46)
This estimate will aggregate the job losses at facilities with reduced or zero output and job gains
at facilities with increased output. Therefore, employee displacement, or job losses, were
estimated by summing the projected change in employment for those facilities that experience a
decrease in output because of the regulations.
Worker displacement costs have traditionally not been measured in economic impact
analyses of regulations. The assumption has usually been that workers costlessly move to new
jobs of equal productivity and earnings, despite numerous studies that show costs borne by
A-143
-------
displaced workers are significant (see Flaim79, Haraermesh80, Maxwell81, and Anderson and
Chandran82).
Building on the work by Adams83 and Topel84, Anderson and Chandran85 constructed
incremental willingness-to-pay measures for job dislocations in a hedonic wage framework. Their
method is analogous to that used by economists to estimate the implicit value of a life using
labor market data (see Moore and Viscusi86). The hedonic displacement cost estimate
conceptually approximates the one-time willingness to pay to avoid an involuntary unemployment
episode. Theoretically, it includes all worker-borne costs net of any off-setting pecuniary or
nonpecuniary "benefits" of unemployment (e.g., unemployment compensation, leisure time
enjoyment). The hedonic displacement cost estimate is a net present value valuation.
According to Bureau of Labor Statistics data, average annual earnings in the paper and
allied products for 1989 was $26,929.87 Using Topel's compensating differential estimate and the
Anderson-Chandran methodology, we estimated that pulp and paper industry workers would
demand an annual compensating differential of $673 ($26,929 * 0.025) to accept a one-point
increase in the probability of displacement. We assumed they would be willing to pay an
equivalent amount to avoid such an increase in the probability of displacement. The implied
statistical cost of an involuntary layoff is thus $67,323 ($673 / 0.01). This value is multiplied by
the total number of employee displacements, or job losses, to estimate the worker displacement
cost of the regulation.
A.5 REFERENCES
1.
2.
3.
4.
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 1990 National Census of Pulp, Paper, and
Paperboard Manufacturing Facilities. Washington, DC. October 31. 1991. '
i
Anderson, D. W., and Ram V. Chandran. Market Estimates of Worker Dislocation
Costs. Economic Letters. 24:381-384. 1987.
Ref. I. ......
U.S. Department of Commerce. Current Industrial Reports: Pulp, Paper, and Board,
1982. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office. 1983. ,
A-144
-------
5. U.S. Department of Commerce. Current Industrial Reports: Pulp, Paper, and Board,
1983 Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office. 1985.
6. U.S. Department of Commerce. Current Industrial Reports: Pulp, Paper, and Board,
1985. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office. 1986.
7. U.S. Department of Commerce. Current Industrial Reports: Pulp, Paper, and Board,
1987. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office. 1989.
8. U.S. Department of Commerce. Current Industrial Reports: Pulp, Paper, and Board,
1989. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office. 1990.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
16.
17.
18.
19.
20.
21.
22.
23.
24.
25.
Ref.
Ref.
Ref.
Ref.
Ref.
Ref.
Ref.
Ref.
Ref.
Ref.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
Organiz
Paper Ii
Amc
Thro
Ame
Thro
Ref.
Ref.
Ref.
Ref.
ria
lUgl
ria
ugh
20.
21.
20.
20.
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). The Pulp and
Paper Industry in the OECD Member Countries. 1992.
American Paper Institute. 1990 Statistics of Paper, Paperboard, and Wood Pulp, Data
Through 1988. New York, NY. 1990.
American Paper Institute. 1988 Statistics of Paper, Paperboard, and Wood Pulp, Data
Through 1987. New York, NY. 1988.
A-145
-------
Associates, Inc. Market Study of Molecular Chlorine-Free and Totally Chlorine-Free
Bleached Paper. Prepared for the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency.
Kline, James E. Paper and Paperboard Manufacturing and Converting Fundamentals.
2nd Edition. San Francisco, Miller Freeman Publications, Inc. 1991.
Varian, Hal R. Microeconomic Analysis. 2nd Edition. New York, NY, W. W. Norton
26.
27.
28.
29.
30.
31.
32.
33.
34.
35.
36.
37.
38.
39.
40.
41.
42.
43.
44.
45.
46.
Ref. 20.
Ref. 21.
Ref. 20.
Associa
Bleachec
Kline, Ja
2nd Edit
Ref. 19.
Ref. 1.
Varian, ]
and Con
Ref. 1.
Ref. 6.
Ref. 7.
Ref. 8.
U.S. Dc{
United S
Ref. 1.
Ref. 8.
Pindyck,
Forecast:
Ref. 4.
Ref. 5.
Ref. 6.
Ref. 7.
Ref. 8.
U.S. Department of Commerce. The 1982 Benchmark Input-Output Accounts of the
United States. Washington, DC, U. S. Government Printing Office. 1991.
Pindyck, Robert S., and Daniel L. Rubinfeld. Econometric Models and Economic
Forecasts. 2nd Ed. New York, NY, McGraw-Hill. 1981.
A-146
-------
47. U.S. Department of Commerce. 1982 Census of Manufactures Industry Series:
Converted Paper and Paperboard Products, Except Containers and Boxes. Washington,
DC, Government Printing Office, 1985.
48. U.S. Department of Commerce. 1987 Census of Manufactures Industry Series:
Converted Paper and Paperboard Products, Except Containers and Boxes. Washington,
DC, Government Printing Office, 1990.
49. U.S. Department of Commerce. 1990 Annual Survey of Manufactures, Value of Product
Shipments. Washington, DC, Government Printing Office, 1992.
50. Ref. 21.
51. Ref. 20.
52. U.S. Department of Commerce. 1990 Annual Survey of Manufactures, Statistics for
Industry Groups and Industries. Washington, DC, Government Printing Office, 1984.
53. U.S. Department of Commerce. 1990 Annual Survey of Manufactures, Statistics for
Industry Groups and Industries. Washington, DC, Government Printing Office, 1986.
54. U.S. Department of Commerce. 1990 Annual Survey of Manufactures, Statistics'for
Industry Groups and Industries. Washington, DC, Government Printing Office, 1988.
55. U.S. Department of Commerce. 1990 Annual Survey of Manufactures, Statistics for
Industry Groups and Industries. Washington, DC, Government Printing Office, 1990.
56. U.S. Department of Commerce. 1990 Annual Survey of Manufactures, Statistics for
Industry Groups and Industries. Washington, DC, Government Printing Office, 1992.
57. Council of Economic Advisors. Economic Report of the President. Washington, DC,
Government Printing Office. February 1992. pp. 368, 370.
58. U.S. Department of Labor. Handbook of Labor Statistics. Bulletin 2340. 1989. pp. 475,
490.
59. U.S. Department of Commerce. Survey of Current Business. 70(7):S-5-S-6. July 1990.
60. U.S. Department of Commerce. Survey of Current Business. 71(11):35. November
1991.
61. Orcutt, Guy H. Measurement of Price Elasticities in International Trade. The Review of
Economics and Statistics. 32(2):117-132. 1950.
62. Love, H. Alan, and Endah Murniningtyas. Measuring the Degree of Market Power
Exerted by Government Trade Agencies. American Journal of Agricultural Economics.
74(3):546-555. 1992.
A-147
-------
63. Ref. 19. ;
64. Ref. 19.
65. Telecon. Ince, Peter, Forest Products Lab, with Murray, Brian , Research Triangle
Institute. January 1993. Transportation costs.
66. Stevens, J.A., and D.M. Adams. Opportunities for Expansion of Alaska's Market Pulp
Exports. Working Paper 34. University of Washington, Center for International Trade in
Forest Products. 1989.
67. Ref. 19
68. Ref. 20.
69. Telecon. U.S. Department of Commerce, Trade Data Inquiries and Control Section, with
Dempsey, Jeanette, Research Triangle Institute. January 1993. Quantity and value of
exports and imports for molded pulp products in 1989.
70. Ref. 20
71. Ref. 20.
72. Ref. 20.
73. Ref. 20.
74. Ref. 8.
75. Ref. 1.
76. Ref. 20.
77. 1992 Lockwood-Post's Directory of the Pulp, Paper and Allied Trades. San Francisco,
Miller Freeman Publications. 1991.
78. Just, Richard E., Darrcll L. Hueth, and Andrew Schmitz. Applied Welfare Economics
and Public Policy. Englewood Cliffs, NJ, Prentice-Hall, Inc. 1982.
79. Flaim, Paul O. Unemployment in 1982: The Cost to Workers and Their Families.
Monthly Labor Review. Feb:30-37. 1984.
80. Hamcrmcsh, Daniel S. What Do We Know About Worker Displacement in the U.S.?
Industrial Relations. 28(l):51-59. 1989.
81. Maxwell. Nan L. Labor Market Effects from Involuntary Job Losses in Layoffs, Plant
Closings: The Role of Human Capital in Facilitating Reemployment and Reduced Wage
Losses. American Journal of Economics and Sociology. 48(2):129-141. 1989.
A-148
-------
82. Ref. 2.
83. Adams, James D. Permanent Differences in Unemployment and Permanent Wage
Differentials. Quarterly Journal of Econometrics. 100(l):29-56. 1985.
84. Topel, Robert H. Equilibrium Earnings, Turnover, and Unemployment: New Evidence.
Journal of Labor Economics. 2(4):500-522. 1984.
85. Ref. 2.
86. Moore, Michael J., and W. Kip Viscusi. Compensation Mechanics for Job Risks.
Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press. 1990.
87. Telecon. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Department of Monthly
Industry Employment Statistics with Dempsey, J., Research Triangle Institute. January 8,
1993. Average hourly earnings, weekly hours, weekly earnings for the pulp and paper
industry in 1989 from Current Employment Statistics, Payroll Survey.
88.
89.
90.
91.
92.
Ref. 1
Ref. 47.
Ref. 48.
Ref. 49.
Ref. 69.
A-149
-------
-------
Subappendix
A-150
-------
-------
TABLE AA-1
NATIONAL CENSUS PROCESS CODE DEFINITIONS88
Code
Process
A
B
C
D
E
F
G
H
I .
J
K
L
M
N
O
P
Q
R
S
T
U
V
W
X
Y
Z
ss
Dissolving Sulfite Pulp
Papergrade Sulfite Pulp
Kraft Pulp v
Dissolving Kraft Pulp
Semi-Chemical Pulp
Groundwood-Chemicai-Mechanical Pulp
Groundwood-Thermo-Mechanical Pulp
Groundwood-Stone Pulp
Groundwood-Chemi-Thermo-Mechanical Pulp
Groundwood-Refiner Pulp
Deink-Fine Papers
Deink-Newspapers
Deink-Tissue Papers
Tissue from Wastepaper .
Wastepaper-Molded Products
Paperboard from Wastepaper
Builders' Paper and Roofing Felt
Newspaper - No Deink
Paper from Wastepaper
Deink - Paperboard
Paperboard and Lincrboard from Broke and Virgin Pulp
Rag and Cotton Pulp
Soda Pulp (Commonly included with sulfate/kraft)
High-Yield Acid Bisulfite
Paper from Waste-paperboard
Other Processes
Synthetic or Semi-Synthetic Glass, Fiberglass, Rayon, Nylon Combinations
A-151
-------
*?
5
3
CO
><
i
s
i
§
w
•iff
a.
Q
0?
i
s
3
EFERENCES: U.S.P
•
CO
CO
0
W
>*
tt
O
O
U
H
s
1
O
of
I
1
1 <- -
Category fron
:, Paperboard,
1 Pulp
•• ^
-*J .Ts
S S-
"S
o.
U3
•o
g S
•a
•1 §>
14
Q y>
-bleached
o
•^
3
CO
^
•s
fate-unbleachi
c?
ibleached
3
c
Printing and writi
paper, uncoated
groundwood
be
_c
•4—*
•c -a
>* £
*11
g"3.-!
11!
Pn a. euo
"o » c ^
1 &|JS
J Q.-5 SC
Uncoated groun
paper (uncoated
containing more
10% mechanical
CN
CN
vo
CN
V)
•0 £r x— .
,— , O _ u-
§ &IU
.| C.-SIB
§1 | 8
§»§ E'i
•0 C M-g
2 3,-| «
o & '« E
D III
cs
T3"2 S,
c 2i K
« « Q.
1978 on, printing
writing paper, Co
and impregnated
^ ^
ait o
.s &
1 a
'&&
•a S
S 8
0 «
CN
CN
A-152
-------
e
u
i
s
03
S
lit
•^ Jfc *
•w a> o
= g-^
^
2 «*- "o
a" o e
^JW
9 -3
C. £
x *C
u ,2
^ w
o
a.
rial Report
"S
f Pu
rd
ties
of
oa
iliti
ional Cens
and Pape
uring F
w
^••2
£ 3
e\
MI
W> 3
1_^
.S a.
e
* -a 3 «
S c 8
« ° -S
8c«
= £8
DO\ j;
T—i t£3
Product Catego
Category
•§
S
i—
CQ
.S3
«
*?1 h
I
OH
e8
E.-S
1 -S £
,±r 03 O
D o. 8
•
•a
•§
-s
*- £ "S
11 =
•SJ5
-------
<•"»%
•*>*
s
o
?
to *
6 o
o *3
p, t/>
S s
"JJ W
p
g
fc^
•c
o
6.
V
g
S
CA
ts
§
^^
en
•c
o
a.
i2
&
§D
f^p -a n.
0 C cB
CO «S CX
00
.s
ii "t*"i
r- 1 ^
*~* *p4 ^
O c *~*
CO 00
CM .C ."5
co '5b"C „,
d# j| 3 g^
^^ CB p-i G3
co D-.t; d,
00
c
'§:
s
»^
t-H
OO
§
{N
00
C-
o
CO
^
~*5
rt -a
bO J2
•S W
&•§
IS C
CO 3
~ C
*O O ^3
•^ ' « S *o
» o S -g
OO ••C "O cB
•— rt r-1 --r
pi j 4) *2j f^
•3"-° S E
Lo § S 55
cs
CO
OO
CN
CN
M
•o o «
•jf « |= -a
*— *
r
-------
^_»
C
o
s™''
J
CO
09
1
B
g
i
fr
|
3
«
P
•e
2
o
D.
i-
o
a
••N
.
Cu
£
ba
O
«!
(A
3
la
tc
Z
O\
C\
•g
S
•e
8, &
c? 3
^•°*
8,1
« >•
a, >
t— -O
e e
•*j
3
W3
t Industrial Report
c
L.
O
r, and Paperboard
factoring Facilities
&g
ft* ^
(•^
U
•c
§.
Jl
V)
t:
1
w
Product Category
ll
n u
D.
Product Category
< «".§
fe s o
V]
T3
x:
6
oc
OJ
«NJ
O
"O
CC
60
J=.
6
^j-
ro
c c^
.£ o
I'll
1 ^^ J>
8.E 'n o
s: ca o
S "E u! **
^^-t CJ 60
u. i-T J= C
U O *•• '3
D. 3 C g
BJ _CT" U. >
S
oc
tN
CM
c 5
M *^^ (/;
^ C *i»
C ji *•* sx
c .E '^ o
ill 1
i/*i
r^i
toX)
111
t/J "*3 CJD M
^ c ^c So
"S ox) c5 e>L
v"l *2
i_- -5 «r w
!M ^ *^*J CS
"£ c. o E
O « tS J2
oo
oc
5
rj
to
f.,3
^ c E
•-> ca e
^- 73 60 §
rt c .E 60
j= w — •
U fen « 60
-* c f .E
Sl^'l
•= "£• c E
v^ "1
r^'
twisting and spinning
stocks
twisting and spinning
stocks
Specialty packaging
oo
s
r-j
60
C
"5b
o
cL
*-•
.2
• 'P
cL
' C/D
f"^
ro
C
o|
8*1
I*!.
s|
f t) "O
1^-8
O w >S
c
IU
cQ t^
.1 S"
c5 p) , _o
.— .
4— »
C
5-
Glassine, greaseproof
and vegetable parchn
oo
oo
§
(N
Glassine, greaseproof
and vegetable
parchment
oc
CO
1_<
6
of
•«3-
•o
C
CO
0
tC
Jj
IU
0
0
cio
o\
Unbleached kraft
T— <
S
CN
i
Unbleached kraft
|
*** C^
s- ^
^
£
•H
ta
o
u
a.
a.
"|"S
•e "i
o.!o
CS C
O^ 3
•jg
•c -a
packaging and industi
converting paperboar
i_~ ^>J
packaging and industi
converting paperboar
;
A-155
-------
o
w
*?
S
CO
?£
H
i
Category from
, Paperfaoard,
Pulp
"* t- "O
f V 0
O OL, O
•§ (2 ^
s «« •«
£ o c
II"
Q..1«
Import/Ex
Stati
«M
i
^
•«
•c
«rf
en
3
•O
XM
>
§>
w
3
y
i
a,
•M
9 V
13
a.
o
we
V
IS
u
•a
3
1
CU
^
w s u
CO
S
6
4>
is
« W)
CO c
if H
r- E
2 8
|
'•3
o
E _
Corrugating
semichemica
T3
c
c* "
II
"3 """ E
o I, r*
"™" ^ "^3 ^>
•ill!
18.g|
D CG O -^*
CO 'C. O O
CO
\o
(N
c
c K
=5 E
3 _3
c "2
1^1 ^
° O es ""•
'§ E. § 5
CO S. S C
5
U3
'P
Recycled fui
paperboard
•a
rt
|
f^_.
u
o
g4
s
^c
rj
•3
es
^
,^
^
||
1
&•
j2
ra
•2
t machine boa
QJ
£
•a
CQ
O
X!
1
•«-*
n>
"2
o
•E'-S
rt _t«
O «— CO
_C ~ 0
O W) cj
« c o
!1|
0 TJ 3
^ .£ a
o
1
^C
r-j
£
"2 -^
CG wj
^ *fc_
^ v "O
ell
IS ^ *
If 1
o — -a
^ .S «
5
2
• VM
CQ
0 C*
&§
Qu^
Constructior
and board, t
paper
u*
o
n
c
BW
u
U-
«-^
c/;
. C
(N
^C
rj
i-
(-
u^>
C-
;j
i_
5;
C
(j
O
13
— i
0
t— i
i — i
VO
01
T3
I—
1
4«»
CQ
"5
«
«N
l—
1>
8
0
4-4
C/)
S-o
^i K)
S x)
1
1
-------
a
U
CQ
Ok
S-e
llf
•** V O
u a. o
•§ £ ^
I'S'S
«J! "
8,3
x -5
w 3
"C M
o
a.
S,
s
"
a
o
^* *o
00 !s
ON c\3
T-I O
8«ll
S-|| g>
^111
»—i cs cs w
\0 Ou O-Un
I
Si
a II
O
•c
a.
M
•a
a
•s
(S-g S
•5 §S
"> -P '«
3 S «
£ JLta
« .? we
U a. B
_ -a 'n
R 8 3
I :-s
5 &3
§D
5
a
o
tj
3
•o
£
Ou
3 «
•«•§
£c3
D-
c
o
t:
S3
O
bO
•S -a
•q >-
.0 o
tu J2
04
O
oo
o\
TJ
T3 * T3
£ a- o
| g£ .
o §^ .
c > c «
« 5 C C
5 111
2 £11
cs
T3
*•• o
^2 o
O-i vi
04
CS
u
•o
e
a.
UcSU
c
O
C3
U
euo
2 55
"E
cs
c
C
t:
cs -O
c- 9
3<£
« -a
j= t>
,£Pt/i ..
MM
r*2'«
« c •
T3
cS
S3
•e g.
S.8
•o c
oo
S 'i
OO
VO
04
TJ
^ «
•£ 3
II
-° 6
11!
U; T-) t; C3
-.
X o ea ns
O X5 CL 0
OO
CS
CO
VO-
04
o
g
cs -a
o c
^ w> =
c-JS
1«-a
^5 s r- y
• v« Cj ^ " rt Q
*«? >*« C O 7T *2
^ ^ C. u O-i WQ
^ -
t) u-
•a = a°-s
O g T3 « 8
« .r nj •— u-.
s-s-iis
03
•5 s
2
in ^ D.
in
*
A-157
-------
*j g e
•a
n
n
O. '£
•s
Q
n.
ca
t
tn
t
1
o
OJC
v
d
1
Cw
U
a
u
o\ •&
OO 4)
c/3 O\ ^3
D T- t ._,
<-~< O
_o [IT ^
tr p^ ^^
03 CO 0-
_a,-a Z o
3 CT3 *X3 ^
iiii
VO O CM ^
irj X 03 C
CN &o
•o ~ .£•
C 43 3
03 X CM'
O _
T3 O ^3
J£ *^^
O •"—• O
t- 3 y-i
0-1 CM><
tf
vo r- o\
S °° t^
CN t— CN
to
swo
«-« «^
u —
•0 -3 =
2 C5 „.
CM ^ J2
J5'*3 «
3 i C-
CM ^JQ £J
•a c 15 v
•SI 2 g
"0 T; w>-C
S .S Si S
^
fi
Q^
CM
1_
cu
03
CM
*J -
4823700000, Molded
or pressed articles oi
«•§§
CM
I
1
O
&1 *> !§
^ £ £
•2 •S^'O
S i- c
Co co *^^
J 0 TJ
119
G 6X)
1st
t5 cC
r . ^j p^^
c *^3 i *•
jrt O ^"|J
tiM CQ
ring Facilities survey
g paperboard. For p
act 40 (unbleached kr
5 .S -o
u t- 8
s: c o
So*-1
S o -o
^- — D
12 "C •§
g •£ 03
!•§•§
<" C S
<$,-— TO
£? *o 2
~" C 03
tj w "°
c$ c tr
•« o
*> tofi c*
^ H"c
p^ ^D
"5" t> ti
^ "5 S.
^**""» ft ^
C^ _ O
2- C ~
C * r«
*^) kfl .-/
CC (^^
2 zj "jp
Ci "^3 ^i
'*~ S ec
^ -j -
•~< (/• «
-s •§ 2 ^
i_ f^'r: §
« g
s 6
3 E
^. o
., O
1 «
"S" £
c -5
•J!
o Q
|co
d the 1990 Annual Si
d pulp, are from the
c w
s "I
s" ^
ON ^^
»— i C*
xi w>
S S
1 IT
O3
03 0
O 3
^ S
_S o
CQ (A
1 2.
a -a
52 <-.
11
,5 „
Us.
'r! ON^
§* OO
N V
•*J ri
6f °O
ti ^
i 52
*•• ^>j
5 <^
§ 1
b' ^
^_ •S'
S E<5
A-158
-------