EPA-230/1 -73-008
AUGUST 1973
          ECONOMIC ANALYSIS
                    OF
   PROPOSED EFFLUENT GUIDELINES


         FEEDLOTS   INDUSTRY
                   QUANTITY
      U.S. ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY
          Office of Planning and Evaluation
             Washington, D.C. 20460
                        \

-------
            This document is available in limited
quantities through the U.S.  Environmental Protection Agency,
      Information Center, Room W-327 Waterside Mall,
                 Washington, D.C.  20460
        The document will subsequently be available
     through the National Technical Information Service,
                Springfield,  Virginia  22151

-------
EPA - 230/1-73-008
                                ECONOMIC ANALYSIS

                                         OF

                        PROPOSED EFFLUENT GUIDELINES


                                FEEDLOTS INDUSTRY
                                   Milton L. David
                                 Richard E.  Seltzer
                                 William D. Eickhoff
                                    August,  1973
                                    Prepared for
                          Office of Planning and Evaluation
                          Environmental Protection Agency
                              Washington,  D.  C.   20460
                          '-•••'.•'<.-nsntal  Protection Agency
                                            Street
                                            6060f

-------
                                          PREFACE
              The attached document is a contractor's study prepared for the Office
              of Planning and Evaluation of the Environmental Protection Agency
              ("EPA").  The purpose  of the study is to analyze the economic impact
              which could result from the application of  alternative effluent limitation
              guidelines and standards of performance to be established  under  sections
              304(b) and 306 of the Federal Water Pollution Control Act,  as amended.

              The study supplements the technical study ("EPA Development Document")
              supporting  the issuance of proposed regulations  under sections 304(b) and
              306.   The Development  Document surveys existing and potential waste
              treatment control methods and technology  within particular industrial
              source categories  and supports promulgation of certain effluent limitation
              guidelines and standards of performance based upon an analysis of the
              feasibility of these guidelines and standards in accordance  with the require-
              ments of sections 3C4(b) and 306 of the Act.   Presented in  the Development
              Document are the investment and operating costs associated with various
  '            alternative control and treatment technologies.  The attached document
"•             supplements  this analysis by estimating the  broader economic effects
 1            which might result from the required application of various control
              methods  and technologies. This study investigates the effect of alter-
              native approaches  in terms of  product price increases, effects upon em-
tv            ployment and the continued viability of affected plants, effects upon
-)            foreign trade and other  competitive effects.
 ~>
i--.            The study has been prepared with the  supervision and review of the Office
 c            of Planning and Evaluation of EPA. This  report was submitted in fulfill-
              ment of Contract No. 68-01-1533,  Task Order  No. 2  by Development
              Planning and Research Associates, Inc.  Work was completed as of
              August,  1973.

              This report is being released and circulated at approximately the same
              time as publication in the Federal Register  of a notice of proposed rule
              making under sections 304(b) and 306  of the Act for the subject point
              source category.  The study has not been  reviewed by EPA and is not
              an official  EPA publication.  The study will be  considered along  with the
              information contained in the  Development  Document and  any comments
              received by EPA on either document before or during proposed rule making
              proceedings necessarv  to establish final regulations.  Prior to final promul-
              gation of regulations, the accompanying study shall have standing in any
              EPA proceeding or court proceeding only  to the extent that it represents
              the views of the contractor who studied the  subject industry.  It cannot be
              cited, referenced,  or represented in any  respect in any  such proceeding
              as a  statement of EPA's views regarding  the subject industry.

-------
                              CONTENTS

                                                                 Page

PARTI:     INTRODUCTION                                    1-1

PART II:    THE FED CATTLE INDUSTRY
                   I.   Fed Cattle Industry Segments              II-1
                            A.  Types of Firms                  II-1
                            B.  Number of Plants and Em-
                                ployment by Segments            11-17
                            C.  Relationship of Segments to
                                Total Industry                    11-18

                  II.   Fed  Cattle Industry Financial Profile      11-26
                           A.   Plants by Segments               11-26
                           B.   Ability to Finance New
                                Investments                      11-31

PART III:    THE HOG INDUSTRY
                   I.   Hog Industry Segments                    III-l
                            A.  Types of Firms                  III-l
                            B.  Number of Plants and Employ-
                                ment by Segments                 III-10
                            C.  Relationship of Segments to
                                the Total Industry                 III-11

                  II.   Hog Industry Financial Profile            III-17
                           A.  Plant by Segments                III-17
                            B.  Ability to Finance New
                                Investments                      111-20

PART IV:    THE DAIRY INDUSTRY
                   I.   Dairy Industry Segments                  IV-1
                           A.  Types of Firms                  IV-1
                            B.  Number of Plants and Employ-
                                ment by Segments                 IV- 10
                            C.  Relationships of Segments to
                                Total Industry                    IV-12

                  II.   Dairy Industry Financial Profile           IV-19
                           A.  Plant by  Segments                IV-19
                           B.  Ability to Finance New
                                Investments                      IV -29

-------
                                                                  age
                      CONTENTS (continued)
PART V:     THE SHEEP INDUSTRY
                  I.   Sheep Industry Segments                  V-l
                           A.   Types of Firms                  V-l
                           B.   Number of Plants and Employ-
                                ment by Segments                V-8
                           C.   Relationships of Segments to
                                Industry                         V-8
PART VI:    THE EGG INDUSTRY
                   I.   Egg Industry Segments                    VI-1
                           A.   Types of Firms                  VI-1
                           B.   Number of Plants and Employ-
                                ment by Segments                VI-11
                           C.   Relationship of Segments to
                                Total Industry                   VI-12

                  II.   Egg Industry Financial  Profile            VI-18
                           A.   Plants by Segments              VI-18
                           B.   Ability to Finance New Invest-
                                ment                            VI-27
PART VII:   THE BROILER INDUSTRY
                   I.   Broiler Industry Segments                VII-1
                           A.   Types of Firms                  VII-1
                           B.   Number of Plants and Employ-
                                ment by Se gments                VII-9
                           C.   Relationships of Segments to
                                Total Industry                   VII-10

                  II.   Broiler Industry - Financial Profile       VII-14
                           A.   Plants by Segment               VII-14
                           B.   Ability to Finance New Invest-
                                ment                            VII-23

-------
                        CONTENTS (continued)
PART VIII:  THE TURKEY INDUSTRY
                   I.   Turkey Industry Segments                 VIII-1
                            A.  Types of Firms                  VIII-1
                            B.  Number of Plants and Employment
                                by Segments                     VIII-9
                            C.  Relationships of Segments to
                                Total Industry                   VIII-10

                  II.   Turkey Industry Financial Profile         VIII-15
                            A.  Plants by Segments              VIII-15
                            B.  Ability to Finance New Invest-
                                ment                            VIII-22
PART IX:    THE DUCK INDUSTRY
                   I.   Duck Industry Segments
                            A.  Types of Firms
IX-1
IX-1
PART X:    GENERAL PRICING
                   A.  Price Determination                      X-l
                   B.  Demand                                  X-6
                   C.  Supply                                    X-l 3

PART XI:   ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS METHODOLOGY     XI-1
                   A.  Price Effects                              XI-4
                   B.  Financial Effects                          XI-5
                   C.  Production Effects                         XI-6
                   D.  Other Effects                              XI-7

PART XII:   COST OF POLLUTION CONTROL                    XII-1
                   A.  State of Art in Pollution Control           XII-1
                   B.  Incremental Costs of Pollution Control     XII-7
PART XIII:  IMPACT ANALYSIS
                   A.  Price Effects
                   B.  Financial Effects
                   C.  Production Effects
                   D.  Employment Effects
                   E.  Resultant Community Effects
XIII-1
XIII-3
XIII-8
XIII-12
XIII-2 5
XIII-2 5

-------
                     CONTENTS  (continued)
PART XIV:   LIMITS OF THE ANALYSIS                         XIV-1
                  A.  General Accuracy                        XIV-1
                  B.  Range of Error                           XIV-2
                  C.  Critical Assumptions                     XIV-2
                  D.  Questions Remaining                     XIV-4

APPENDIX

-------
                    PART I:  INTRODUCTION
The feedlot industry as specified in the Task Order RFP includes the
following SIC industries:

       SIC  0241   Dairy farms
       SIC  0251   Broilers, Fryers  and Roaster Chickens
       SIC  0252   Chicken, Eggs
       SIC  0253   Turkey and Turkey Eggs
       SIC  0254   Poultry Hatcheries
       SIC  0259   Poultry and Eggs , not elsewhere classified
       SIC  0211   Beef Cattle Feedlots
       SIC  0213   Hogs

A brief description of each industry is as follows:

SIC  0241 Dairy farms

Dairy farms wer  defined as farms with cows kept for milk.   The Census
of Agriculture  reported 452,052  farms with milk cows in 1969.  These units
ranged in size  from one to a thousand or more milk cows.
    O

Milk production units are basically small with 40-50 cow units prevailing.
Producers are independent entrepreneurs controlling  all assets  used in
milk production and selling their output in a free market.

Dairying is  an important sector  of the farm economy with farm  sales of
dairy products equalling $6.8 billion  in 1972.   Sales represented 12.9
percent of all farm income.

SIC  0251 Broilers,  Fryers and Roasters

Broiler feedlots were defined as farm production units producing broilers
for  the commercial market.   This definition of broiler feedlots  includes
birds produced as fryers and  roasters.
                                 1-1

-------
In 1969 the Census of Agriculture reported 28,704 farms with broilers.
These  farms ranged in size from those selling 8,000 to over 100,000
birds annually.  Production is being concentrated on fewer units with
large scale enterprises evolving. Production from farm flocks is
insignificant.

Broiler production units are part of an overall integrated system.
Nearly all birds are grown by farmers (growers) under contract with
a contractor  (integrator).

Management  decisions are made by the contractor with farmers making
the basic  decisions to  grow or not grow broilers and with what contractor.

Farm value of broilers equalled $1.5 billion in 1971.   Receipts to growers
are estimated to be 15 percent of total value or $225 million.

SIC  0252 Chicken  Eggs

The chicken egg industry was defined as farmers (producers) producing
eggs for table egg consumption.  The  1969 Census of Agriculture reported
279, 899 farms producing table eggs.

Egg producers have been and are increasing in size.   Farm flocks are
decreasing with production becoming concentrated in units of  3,200 birds
or more.  Increased vertical integration or coordination is occurring with
over half of all eggs now being produced under some type of production or
marketing agreement.

Farm value of eggs equalled $1.8 billion in 1971.  These  sales repre-
sented 3.  5 percent of total farm income.

SIC 0253  Turkey and Turkey Eggs

Turkey feedlots are defined as production units producing birds for the
commercial meat market.  In 1969, The Census of Agriculture reported
5,424  farms  with  turkeys.  One  half of these  units sold more  than 8,000
birds and accounted for 95 percent of  U.S. production.

Turkey production is a highly coordinated industry with nearly all birds
grown under some type of production or marketing agreement between
growers and processors.

Farm  sales of turkeys equalled $501 million dollars in 19V 1 and comprised
0. 9 percent of total farm income.


                                1-2

-------
SIC  0254  Poultry Hatcheries

Poultry hatcheries were excluded from this report for three  reasons: (1)
they do not fit the definitions for feedlots;  (2)  their effluent discharge is
not considered significant; and (3)  costs for effluent control were not
provided by sub-contractors.

SIC  0259  Poultry and Eggs Not Elsewhere Classified

Ducks were included in this  segment of other  poultry.  Limited infor-
mation is available on duck feedlots.  Therefore analyses of  the structure
of duck production is limited.

Limited data showed that duck production equalled 13 million head in
1969.  This production was achieved by about 150 producers  concentrated
in five states.

Production is assumed to  be  highly integrated with control vested in
the hands of a limited number of individual firms or cooperatives.

SIC  0211  Beef Cattle Feedlots

Beef cattle feedlots were defined as all production units feeding cattle on
grain and concentrates for commercial slaughter. In 1972,  the USDA
reported 154, 536 feedlots fitting the preceding definition.

Over 98 percent of all feedlots were classified as farmer feeders,  mar-
keting 38 percent of all cattle from feedlots with a capacity of under  1,000
head.  Commercial feedlots, with capacity of 1,000 or more head
produced 62 percent  of all fed cattle.

In 1971 sales of cattle and calves equalled $19.4 billion or 36.5 percent
of all farm income.  Sales were nearly three  times greater than farm
income from dairy and about four times greater than sales of poultry
and poultry products.

SIC  0213  Hogs

Hog feedlots  are defined as a farm or  production unit with hogs.  In 1969
the Census of Agriculture reported 532,292 farm production units with hogs.
Hog production is concentrated in the Midwest,  but all states do have some
production units.   The most common size  units are those with 100-500
head inventories.

Hogs  rank second to  cattle as a source of farm  income.  In 1971 farm
sales of hogs equalled $4. 1 billion,  7.8 percent of total farm sal ;s.

                                 1-3

-------
SIC	Sheep

Sheep feedlots were included as an additional feedlot segment.  The  1969
Census  of Agriculture reported 123,858 farms with sheep.   No data  are
available on the number of farms which only feed lambs.

Sheep are relatively insignificant as a  source of farm income.  In 1971,
sales of sheep from fa rms equalled $313 million,  0.6 pe rcent of total
farm sales.

Due  to time limitations and difficulty in obtaining data on production costs,
financial profile data is not included in this report.

Analyses of industry segments and price dete rmination we re made for
eight different types of feedlots.  Financial profiles were developed  for
six feedlots with sheep and duck production units being excluded due to
lack of  data.

Reports were arranged in the following order:

        Part II:     The Fed Cattle Industry
        Part III:    The Hog Industry
        Part IV:    The Dairy Industry
        Part V:     The Sheep Industry
        Part VI:    The Egg Industry
        Part VII:   The Broiler Industry
        PartVIII:   The Turkey Industry
        Part IX:    The Duck Industry
        Part X:     General Pricing
        Part XI:    Methodology
                                1-4

-------
             PART II:   THE FED CATTLE INDUSTRY


               I.   FED CATTLE INDUSTRY SEGMENTS


                        A.  Types of Firms

Cattle feeding, a relatively old enterprise, has undergone rapid and
far-reaching changes since World War II.  During the post World
War II period,  fed cattle marketings in the United States have more
than doubled and recent trends  suggest a continual increase can be ex-
pected.  Cattle feeding today involves more than  154, 000 feedlots which
marketed nearly 28 million fed cattle in 1972.

Cattle feedlots are common  throughout the United States, but in the past
they have been predominately located in the Corn Belt areas where there
was  a combination of feed supplies, feeder cattle, markets, and other
resources.  During the past 15 years, concentrated areas of large-scale
commercial cattle feeding have developed in California,  Arizona,  Texas,
the Plains States and Colorado.

Cattle feeders  can be divided into two basic types:  the farmer feeder and
the commercial feeder.  Farmer feeders  are  defined as operators of
feedlots with capacity less than 1, 000 head.  In 1972 there were 152, 429
of these farmer feeders, representing 98.6 percent of the total number of
feedlots.  There are  substantial numbers  of farmer feeders in most regions,
but they are of greatest relative importance in the Corn Belt, Northern
Plains and Lake States.  Usually,  farmer feeders use their feedlot as a
supplement to other farming  or ranching enterprises.

Commercial cattle feedlots are defined as feedlots  with a capacity of 1,000
head or more.   In  1972, there were 2, 107 commercial feedlots, which accounts
for only  1.4 percent of the total number of feedlots.  However,  this  1.4
percent of all feedlots accounted for over  60 percent of all the fed cattle
marketed in 1972.  Commercial feedlots tend to  be a highly-specialized,
efficient operation, ranging  from 1, 000 head capacity to over 100, 000
head.  These feedlots generally dominate  output  in the newer cattle-
feeding areas -- the Plains States, Colorado,  Texas,  Arizona,  and California.

Although the  cattle-feeding industry has produced a steadily-increasing
number of fed cattle, it has  done  so with fewer feedlots.  Since 1962,
the number of farmer feeders has declined by nearly 77, 000 feedlots.
During this same time  period the number  of commercial lots increased by
668 and the number of fed cattle marketed increased by 12.3 million.
                                II-1

-------
Number and Size of Production Units

In 1972, there were  154,536 cattle feedlots in the United States.  Of
these 152, 429 or 98. 6 percent were farmer feeders with capacity below
1, 000 head.  The remainder, or 2, 107 feedlots,  were commercial
feedlots operating with capacity of 1, 000 head or more.  This represented
a 35. 5 percent decrease in the number of farmer feeders since 1962,
while the number of  commercial feedlots increased 46.4 percent.  When
considering the commercial feedlot increase by capacity category,  feed-
lots  with capacity of 32, 000 head or more increased the most, nearly
twenty times (Table  II-1),.

Farmer feeders accounted for 99.4 percent of the total number of feedlots
in 1962 and marketed 63.6 percent of all fed cattle.  In 1972,  farmer
feeders accounted for 98.6 percent of all feedlots but only marketed 38.4
percent of  all fed cattle.   Thus,  there has been a tendency for farmer
feeders to  use  his resources elsewhere and let the commercial feedlot
feed cattle.

Volume of  Marketings

Since 1965, the number of fed cattle marketed has increased by forty-
seven percent.  In 1972 nearly 28 million fed cattle were marketed, an
increase of nearly nine million head since 1965.

                             Number Marketed            Percent Change
Year                           (1, OOP head)                1965 to 1972

1965                              18,992
1966                              20,655                       9
1967                              21,986                      16
1968                              23,691                      25
1969                              24,998                      32
1970                              25,961                      37
1971                              26,403                      39
1972                              27,927                      47

To supply  the cattle feeding industry with feeder  cattle,  there was a
corresponding increase in the number of beef cows on farms in the  United
States.  Since  1955, the number of beef cows has increased by fifty-five
percent, from 24.9  million to 38.7 million head.
                               II-2

-------
   Table II-1.   Number of cattle feedlots and fed cattle marketed,  by size of feed'ot capacity,
                                   1962 and 1972, 23 principal states. I/

Feedlot Capacity

< 1,000 head
1,000 - 1,999
2,000 - 3,999
4,000 - 7,999
8,000 - 15,999
16,000 - 31,999
32,000 or more
Total
1962
Number
Feedlots Percent

229,365 99-38
766 0. 33
365 0.16
184 0.08
101 0.04
20 0. 01
3
230,804 100.00
1972
Cattle
Marketed
1,000
9,271
843
817
1,116
1,681
636
196
14, 560
Percent
Number
Feedlots
Percent
Cattle
Marketed
Percent
1,000
63.
5.
5.
7.
11.
4.
1.
100.
6
8
6
7
5
4
4
0
152,429
912
4H4
311
216
125
59
154,536
98.
0.
0.
0.
o.
0.
0.
100.
64
59
31
20
14
08
04
00
10,
1,
1,
2,
3,
4,
4,
26,
275
283
353
181
254
191
298
835
38.4
4. 8
5. 0
8. 1
12. 1
15. 6
16. 0
100. 0
I/ Number of feedlots with 1,000 or more capacity is number of lots operating anytime during year.
   Number under 1,000 head capacity is number at end of year.
Source: Cattle on Feed Report, U.S.D.A. ,  S. R. S.

-------
                                Beef Cows                Change Index
Year                 ~       (million head)               (1955  = 100)

1955        .                     24.9                       100
I960                             25.7                       103
1965                             33.4                       134
1970                             36.4                       146
1972                             38.7                       155

This increase in beef cow numbers can be traced to a shift from dairy to
beef production in the Corn Belt, Lake States, and Northeast, from a
shift in land use from row crops to pasture production,  and from the
reclamation of forest lands in the Southeastern States.

Age  of Production Facilities

There is limited information pertaining to the age of production facilities
for cattle feedlots.  It is assumed that the entrance of new feedlots or
expansion of older feedlots is related  to age.  In a report by R.A.  Dietrich
of Texas A. and M.  University, ages  of feedlots facilities in Texas and
Oklahoma were characterized by the following quotation:

      "Large, highly mechanized,  commercial feedlots are  relatively
        new in Texas and Oklahoma.  Fifty percent  or more of the current
        feeding facilities in the Southern Plains were constructed during
        or after I960, Table II-2. Many feedlots with  less than 1,000
        head capacity, or small feedlots,  are integrated with farming
        or ranching  operations.  In general, more of these small lots
        remain at original capacity or technological levels than  do feedlots
        with a capacity of 1, 000 head or more since they are often a
        supplementary enterprise.  However,  feedlots of  all siz,es, have
        been and are expanding their feeding facilities as  their capital
        position and management practices improve sufficiently for making
        decisions and accepting the responsibilities  associated with
        increasingly larger feeding operations. "_L'

The  study by  Dietrich helps to  emphasize  the tendency for the larger feedlots
to have relatively new facilities.  The  operators  of these lots, in an effort
to be more  efficient,  tend to  reinvest their capital in the  feedlot and thus
maintain a modern  efficient production facility.   On the other hand,  the
farmer feeder will  use  predominately what facilities he already has  and
unless he wants to expand his cattle feeding capacity, he  will be reluctant
to modernize  his cattle operation.
i' Dietrich, Raymond A., "The Texas-Oklahoma Cattle Feeding Industry,"
   Texas Agr.  Exp. Sta., Bui. 1079, Dec.,  1968.
                                  II-4

-------
         Table II-2.  Year in which present type of feeding operations
                      were established,  by size of feedlot,
                         Texas and  Oklahoma,  1966-1967
Sfote and year
Less than
1,000-head
 capacity
 1,000 to
1,999-head
 capacity
 2,000 to
4,999-head
 capacity
 5,000 to
9,999-head
 capacity
10,000-head-
 and-more
  capacity
                                                                                            Total
Texas:

  Before 1945
  1945-49
  1950-54
  1955-59
  1960-64
  After 1964

   Total

Oklahoma
  Before 1945
  1945-49
  1950-54
  1955-59
  1960-64
  After 1964

   Total
8.8
11.8
5.9
20 6
44.1
8.8
1000
7 7
307
15 4
15 4
23 1
7 7
0
0
0
400
46.7
13 3
100 0
14 3
0
14 3
14 3
285
28 6
5 9
0
0
32 3
50 0
11 8
100 0
12 5
0
12 5
250
50 0
0
0
11.8
11.7
294
29.4
17 7
100 0
0
0
50 0
0
50 0
0
5.0
100
5.0
15 0
45 0
200
100 0
0
0
25 0
0
50 0
25 0
7.5
9 9
5 2
23 1\
44 4/
99
1000
8.0
28.5
15 4
15 6
24 3
8 2
                     100 0
                                   10 00
                                                 i 00 0
                                                               100 0
                                                                             100 0
                                                                                           100 0
     Source:  Dietrich, Raymond A. ,  "The Texas-Oklahoma Cattle Feeding
               Industry,"  Texas Agr.  Exp. Sta. ,  Bui.  1079, Dec.,  1968.
                                             n-5

-------
Most all of the cattle feeding states have had increases in the number of
the larger feedlots.  However,  Texas, Nebraska, Iowa, Kansas, Colorado,
California and Oklahoma have shown the most significant increases in the
past ten years (Table II-3).

The growth in cattle feeding has occurred in the larger feedlots requiring
more recent investments than in farmer-feeder feedlots.   Therefore, we
estimate the average age of commercial feedlots to be 10-15 years. Age
of farmer-feeder feedlots is estimated to be 15-20 years.

Location of Major Producing Segments

Fed beef production is predominately located in two regions: the Central
and Southern Corn Belt states; and the Southwest.  The Corn Belt states
have historically always been leaders in fed beef production while the
Southwest has more recently developed into a major beef area.  Of the
ten leading states  in fed cattle marketings,  six were located in or adjacent
to the Corn Belt region.  These include:  Nebraska, Iowa,  Kansas, Illinois,
Minnesota,  and Oklahoma.  These six states accounted for forty-eight percent
of fed cattle marketings with feedlot operations  accounting for  sixty percent
of all feedlots.

The Southwest included four of the ten leading fed cattle producing states.
These states (Texas, Colorado,  California  and Arizona) produced thirty-
six percent of fed  cattle marketed,  doing so with only two percent of all
cattle feedlots.

Level of Technology and Efficiency

The fed beef industry can be described as an industry that has  had recent
developments in improving efficiency through the use  of modern technological
improvements.  Recent improvements include the implementation of com-
pletely automated  feed handling systems.  The feed is ground at the feedlot's
mill and distributed to the various lot's feed bunks by way of conveyors
and augers.  Feed is usually handled in bulk form and the feed  rations are
scientifically formulated by the feedlot1 s nutritionist.   This has caused a
decrease in the man hours required per  head of beef,  especially on the
larger, more efficient feedlot.   The nutritional approach to feed formulation
has enabled the feeder to provide a better feed resulting in less feed con-
sumption per pound of gain.

The degree to which a feedlot takes advantage of technological  improvements
is dependent upon the size of the operation.  Technological adaptation gen-
erally requires a  fairly substantial operation if the  producer is to realize
the cost-reducing benefits of the new technology.  A feed mill investment,
                                II-6

-------
I
-J
    Table II-3.  Percentage change in number of feedlots, by size,  1962 to 1972, for the ten leading states.
Percentage Change
State
Texas
Nebraska
Iowa
Kansas
Colorado
California
Illinois
Minnesota
Arizona
Oklahoma
Less
than
1,000
-18.7
-30.6
-28.3
-50.7
-48.7
-69.2
-48.6
-41.7
-92.6
-78.7
1,000-
1,999
-45.9
50.9
169.7
50,0
116.1
-60.4
133.3
70.6
-83.3
-38.4
2, 000-
3,999
-36.7
86.7
1766.7
112.5
157.8
-49.0
(6)
50.0
-72.0
-0. 1
4, 000-
7,999
25.8
75.0
(19)
116.7
125. 0
9.7
66.7
-
-61.9
16.7
8, 000-
15, 999
71.4
81.8
(6)
244.4
64.3
16.2
-
-
-27.2
(H)
16,000- 32,000
39,999 and over Total
(38) • (24) -15.1
(8) (4) -29.3
-28.0
(16) (5) -50.0
(11) (5) -36.6
76.9 233.3 -49.1
-48.4
-41.6
(9) (9) -72.0
-77.0
    Source: Cattle on Feed, U.S.D.A., S. R. S.

    Parenthesis denote an increase from zero to the number of feedlots in the parenthesis.

-------
 for example, must be spread over a large feedlot capacity if an operator
 is  to realize  substantial reductions in total cost-per-pound-of-gain.  The
 farmer-feeders located in the Corn Belt States, generally will not have
 sufficient volume to take advantage of new developments.  In fact, some
 predict that many farmer-feeders  -will leave  the industry when cost and
 labor-reducing technology is  generally adopted.  It is felt that those
 regions which have the economic structures  compatible with  large-scale
 commercial-type feeding will gain the  greatest advantages from techno-
 logical advances.  —'

Level of Integration

The feed cattle industry with respect to the  extent of integration within
the  industry should be separated into two types of feedlot operations --
the  farmer feeder and the commercial feedlot.

Relatively few farmer feeders are integrated  to any great extent.  Usually,
the  farmer feeder buys his cattle according to the amount of  grain he
produces.  If  he has a good year, production-wise for his grains,  he
may purchase a few more head than usual to put in his feedlot.  Basically,
the  farmer feeder will own all the cattle in his feedlot.  A  study by the
National Commission on Food Marketing  indicated that  94. 5 percent of
the  farmer feeders interviewed in a fifteen  state survey owned their
feedlot's cattle (Table II-4).

The farmer feeder usually has alternative opportunities to direct  his
labor if he wishes to leave the feedlot business.  Because of this, these
feeders will hesitate to become involved with  any major integration
centered around their feedlot.  The large commercial feedlot, who has
fewer alternative  opportunities, will tend to be more  acceptable to some
degree  of integration.

Commercial feedlots are highly specialized operations, ranging in
capacity from 1, 000 to over 100, 000 head.  They may be  single-enterprise
operations, or they may be  integrated with  such other activities as  grain
production, feed manufacturing, feeder-cattle production,  and meat
packing.  The feedlot operation may own the  cattle fed or custom-feed
them for others.  The larger  feedlots' cattle  tend to be owned by  more
than one individual mainly due to the large amounts of capital involved.
Ownership of commercial feedlots  ranges from sole-proprietorships  to
corporate  farms,  including  cooperatives.
 _' Goodwin, John W. ,  "Cattle Feeding:  An Analysis of Oklahoma
    Opportunities," Oklahoma State University, Processed Series P-488,
    January,  1965.

                                II-8

-------
       Table II-4. Percentage of cattle numbers marketed,  by types  of feeding
           arrangement,  by capacity groups,  sample data for 15 states,
                                     1964I/
          Capacity group
 Owned   '  „      '   Other
        :  Custom :           : , ,
   by        ,  ,    arrange-   Lnknown
        *    T C Q  *       "    "
fcedloL  '        '  raents 2/
Farmer  feeders.
Commercial feeders:
  1,000-1,999
  2,000-4,999
  5,000-9,999
  10,000-14,999
  13,000-39,999
  20,000-29,999
  30,000-49,999
  50,000  and over



V9 	
y 9 	
99 	
yy 	

	 : 85 . 9
	 : 74 .9
	 : 55. 7
	 : 48.9
500
	 : 49 . 8
	 : 47.1
	 : 48.5
12 3
21.0
40. 2
46 8
4A 3
44.5
41. 3
23.]
                   .1.9
                   3. a
                   5. 7
                   1.1
                  11.6
    Total  (sample),
56.4
          37.)
4.0
                                     Total


94.5 3.8


1.0 0,7 100.0
1.4
2.2
1.0
2.0
	
4.6
	
	
100,0
200.0
100.0
100.0
aoo.o
100.0
100,0
100.0
]00.0
  _!/  Tlie 15 States are Iowa, Xcbr. , i'.ans.,  Okla., Tex,, Colo., Mont.,  Idaho, U'yo. ,
l/tah,  N. Mox. , Arir.,,  Calif., Orej;. , and Wash.
  2/  Consists prir./irily of  partncrsajp arrangorient.P.


       Source:  National Commission on Food Marketings,  "Organization and
                Competition in the  Livestock and Meat Industry,"  Tech. Study
                No.  1, June, 1966.
                                           II-9

-------
 Besides feeding their own cattle, many commercial feedlots operate under
 some different arrangements.  Some of these arrangements are as follows:

 Custom feeders - These feeders perform the  service of feeding cattle for
 a fee,  without taking ownership to the cattle.  They are found principally
 in regions with large numbers of commercial feedlots -- primarily Cali-
 fornia, Arizona, Colorado, and the Plains States {Table II-5).

Custom feeding arrangements  are varied and numerous; however, four
systems are relatively common.JV In one,  the custom operator buys the
cattle in his own name.  The'client then executes an agreement to buy
the cattle when they are ready for slaughter, paying a cost equal to the
original purchase price of the  feeder  cattle, plus all feeding, handling,
and interest charges.^.' Usually the client is required to make  a down-
payment of 20 to 30 percent of the purchase price of the feeder  cattle.

The  feed mark-up system  involves a basic feed charge,  plus a mark-
up to cover feed handling and grinding and labor costs.  Usually there
is  an extra charge  of $1.50 to  $3.00 per head to cover vaccination,
medication,  branding,  dehorning,  and dipping._£/

A third custom-feeding  system is based on a basic feed charge  per  ton
of feed,  plus an additional 5 to 6 cents per head per day to cover handling,
yardage,  feed grinding, and similar expenses.  Also,  an additional charge
is  added, as in the mark-up system,  to cover medication,  vaccination,  etc._l'

A fourth plan is based on a charge per pound of gain.  Actually,  few
feedlots use this arrangement, however, as rate and efficiency of gain
of feeder cattle  vary,  as does  the  effect of uncontrollable  factors such
as weather and disease.^./
!/ Cattle Feeding in the United States," Agricultural Report No.  186,  U. S.D.A.
   E.R.S., 1970.
?L' Hopkins,  John A. and Kramer, Robert C.,  "Cattle Feeding in California, "
   Bank of America, San Francisco,  Feb., 1965.
_' Dietrich, Raymond  A. ,  "The Texas-Oklahoma Cattle Feeding Industry, "
   Texas Agr. Exp.  Sta. , Bui. 1079, Dec., 1968.

-  Ib*d>
I/ "Cattle Feeding in the United States, " op. cit.
                              ii-

-------
Table II-5. Percentage of feedlot numbers and percentage of cattle marketings,
       by types of feeding arrangement, by States or areas, 1964.
                                                         nir-.Ders under
                                            feeding arrangements
lype 01 leeaioL oy
State or area



Commercial feedlots: 3.'

Texas 	 	 	





: All
: owned
'•

	 : 93. 3
	 : 71.4
	 : 47.9
	 : 54.1
	 : 7i3.1
	 : 69.4
	 53.1
	 : 47.1
	 : 65.9
: All :
: custom :


2.5
2.5
22.9
4.0
2.4
2.8
A.I
9.1
2.1
Some |
custom
ii :


2.5
21.0
27.1
35.5
19.5
25.0
32.6
33.1
27.7
Other
2/


1.7
5.1
2.1
6.4

2.8
10.2
10.7
4,3
' Total


100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
15 States.
                                   59.1
6.0
28.7
6.2
100.0
 !_/  Includes combination of  custom and owned and custom and other.
 2/  Includes other arrangements and coruinationb of owacu and other.
 _3/  Sai.iple data.

Source:  Williams, WillardF., "Structure and Conduct of the Commercial
         Cattle Feeding Industry", Supp. Study No. 1 to Tech. Study No. 1,
         Organization and Competition in the Livestock and Meat Industry,
         National Commission on Food Marketing,  June,  1966.
                                   11-11

-------
 Custom feeding is usually considered to be in direct relationship with
 the  size of cattle feedlot.  Custom feeders at present account for an
 estimated forty-five percent of commercial feedlot1 s cattle, having a
 capacity of between 5,000 and  50,000 head (Table II-4).  Feedlots with
 over 50,000 head capacity do less  custom feeding with an estimated  20
 percent of their feedlot capacity utilized in this manner.

 Principally, the owners of custom-fed cattle were cattle feeders which
 accounted for forty-five percent of the cattle that were  custom-fed.  Far-
 mers or ranchers accounted for twenty-eight percent and meat packers
 and packer-buyers accounted for eighteen percent.  The remainder of the
 custom-fed cattle were owned  by livestock marketing agencies,  non-farm
 agricultural businesses and food retailers  (Table II-6).

 Packer-Feeders - Some cattle are fed in packer-owned feedlots or  in
 custom feedlots for packers  and associated interests.   Packers  owned
 about seven percent of all fed cattle marketed in  1965,  and packer-
 associated  interests accounted for four percent (Table II-7). —'  More
 than eighty percent of packer-fed  cattle in  1965 were produced in the
 Western States, with  only a few being produced in the Lake States,
 Corn Belt or Pennsylvania.

In 1971,  there were 122 packer-feeders which marketed 1, 173, 000 fed
cattle.  This is  a decrease in the number of packer-feeders of twenty-
six percent  since 1954,  however, the number of fed cattle marketed by
packer-feeders  increased 208 percent during  the  same time period.   Even
with this increase, the packer-feeders percent of total fed  marketings
declined from 6 percent in 1954 to four and a half percent in 1971 (Table II-8).

Packers have several reasons for  entering  into the cattle feeding business.
They do this to have: (1) a  reliable  supply of slaughter cattle -- particularly
on Monday mornings  --to  utilize their labor force fully; (2) a source of
particular grades and weights of cattle needed but sometimes not available
on the open  market; (3) a ready source of cattle for unexpected or excep-
tionally large orders;  and (4) a  supply of slaughter cattle during  off-seasons ._£'
—  "Cattle Feeding in the United States," Agricultural Report No.  186,
    ERS, USDA,  1970.
^J  Ibid.
                                 11-12

-------
         Table II-6.  Percentage of cattle fed on custom basis,  by principal occupations
           of owners,  feedlots of 1,000 or more head capacity, 15 states,  1964.1'
           custom-fed cattle
Farmer or rancner	
Cattle feeder	
^onfanr: agricultural ousiaess	
Meatpacxers and packer-buyers	
Other livestock i.iariceting agencies	
Food retailers.
Others 2/	
  Total	
.r.t-c ci.sto.T. fed ir. feedlots
 1,UOU or more neaci
        27.8
        45.4
         1.5
        17.9
         4 .b
          .6
         2.2
       100.0
        —' For States,  see Table 1-5.
        _' Includes lending agencies,  nonagricultural business firms, professional
           workers, and investors.
        Source:  National Commission on Food Marketing,  Organization and
                  Competition in the Livestock and Meat Industry,  Tech.  Study
                  No.  1, June  1966.
                                            11-13

-------
Table II-7. Marketings of fed cattle,  volume of packer-feeding and packer-feeding as a percentage
                    of  fed cattle marketings,  by regions, 1965.
I Fed
Ki:gl'J


• •, i'i) s .' 1 11 	 	 	 : 379
>.!)••.,' , j 	 : l 144
',.•'•:•; 	 : OJ'J

. . i i K)'.I,.I. . 	 : 2 2!'' il:;,.. iii'i i I .1 1 ,i I l.-.i , amt d f ! 1 1 lilLliE i> ! J><1
2' ",N-., :<•>. \'i. J.C., S.C. Ark. an'!
j/ 'l.'lai l.i !"i ','-> States and aci_oiiiiL'» fo
Source: Crom, Richard J. , "Revised
Livestock and Meat Situation
0.4
13.1
61.2
79.5
i ci j 2
232.8
29.2
t>7.5
Si. 9
153.1
310.3
72 . 2
1,291.4
covers supj
ckers.
Associated
| interests I/
l.CL'O ]
3.b
"J .2
^0.3
cO.^
23.3
4 y . 2
40. 3
2 0 "_ . 0
15. 1
2/o.G
15.4
757.3 1,
.g
•otal
,000
4.2
22. 3
101.5
159.9
213.7
281.0
'; 4 . 5
1 ' 3 i
5.^.3
O / » .
Oj'-i.2
Packer freeing as percentage
Packers : " 	 ^ '~ . : Total

0.3 ' j . . 3.6
] . 2 j "" n
1.0 .7 1.7
14.2 :-... 23.i-
li.9 3.1 1S.O
7.7 10.5 l'J.2
5.9 IT. 6 22.5
12.6 1.9 1-..5
2J.5 2.0 ' 22.5
13.6 12.2 -i-.'i
33.1 7 .' ..? .2
b.3 i.j. 10.9
rate feeding by ovr.e rr , directors, officers, erplcyees, r.c..-
r inosl fed r:a-ketinf? in the United States.
Estimates of Marketings and Placements of Cattle on Feed, " U.S.
, LMS-155, p. 30-32, May, 1967.
      U.S.D.A., Dec.  1972.

-------
Table  H-8. Number of packers feeding cattle and number of head fed compared
  with total fed marketings of cattle in 39 states, 1954-1971.
Year :

1954
1955
1956
1957
1958
1959
1960
1961 31
1962
1963
W64
1965 3/
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
f. ,Y,:,,j i

165 •
161
157
151
176
157
165
206
215
211
190
204
202
198
174
154
140
C.ILI la
IjV >
  • : Source: Packers and Stockyards Administration, "Packers and Stockyards Resume, " Vol. X, No. 13, U.S.D.A., Dec. 1972. 11-15

  • -------
    Retail food chains - These have occasionally engaged in cattle feeding and
    slaughter, but they accounted for only a small part of all fed-cattle marketings.
    In 1964,  three major food chains accounted for most of the  719, 000 head
    slaughtered by retail food chains and they fed only 64, 000 head,  which was
    less than half a percent of fed-cattle marketings for 39 states._'
    
    Cooperative Feedlots  -  Cooperative feedlots represent an extremely small
    sector of the cattle-feeding industry.  On January 1,  1969,  there were only
    seven cooperative feedlots in  operation.  According to the Farmer Cooperative
    Service, these feedlots were located in Arizona,  California,  Utah,  Montana,
    Oklahoma, Georgia.,  and South Carolina.  At that time, the total capacity for
    these feedlots was about  50,000 head.fL/
    
    Level of Diversification
    
    The alternate opportunities for a fed cattle producer's facilities and resources
    are dependent on the size of the operation.  The decision to diversify is much
    easier to make  for a farmer  feeder who has a small feedlot than for a large
    commercial feedlot operator.
    
    
    The farmer feeder often  will have a minimum investment in feedlot
    facilities and  usually it is possible for him to reorient himself toward
    another enterprise without major difficulties.  The farmer  feeder
    uses his feedlot to provide himself with  work that can be  done during
    the winter months as well as provide extra income.  Since the farmer
    feeder has other enterprises such as hogs or cash crops, he  can
    concentrate on these enterprises if he decides to eliminate  cattle from
    his farming operation.
    
    The commercial feedlot operator  is limited with what he can do with
    his facilities.  High investments in feed mills,  pens,  and feed bunks
    are common in commercial feedlots and alternate uses of these  facilities
    are few.  Therefore the commercial feeder will attempt to  stay  in opera-
    tion as long as he can.
     —'  National Commission of Food Marketing, "Organization and Compe-
        tition in the Livestock and Meat Industry,"  Tech. Study No. 1,
        June, 1966.
     —  "Cattle Feeding in the United States, " op. cit.
                                    H-16
    

    -------
            B.  Number of Plants and Employment by Segments
    
    In the United States there are about  154, 000 cattle  feedlot operators.  Of
    these,  nearly ninety-nine percent are farmer feeders with feedlot capacity
    of less than 1, 000 head.
    
                     Size                     Number of Operators
    
                <1, 000 Head                          152, 429
                 1, 000 - 1, 999.                           912
                 2, 000 - 3, 999                           484
                 4, 000 - 7,999                           311
                 8, 000 - 15, 999                          216
                16, 000 - 31, 999                          125
                32, 000 or more                           59
                      Total                     -    154,536
    
    The labor requirement is dependent upon the size of the  feedlot operation.
    A majority  of the  farmer feeders use their feedlot for  supplemental
    income.  These operations are usually sized according to the ability  of the
    operator  and his family to supply the  necessary labor.  This way the farmer
    can utilize his time  when not working on his other  enterprises such as
    crops.
    
    
     Commercial feedlots usually consist of a  feedlot manager, hired labor,
     and if the operation is large enough,  a bookkeeper.  It is assumed that
     for feedlots up to 5,000 head capacity,  the feedlot manager helps with
     labor's duties.  For operations greater than 5,000 head capacity,  the
     manager will concern himself predominately with management duties.
     It is also assumed that feedlots with capacity of more than 8,000 head
     will have a bookkeeper.
    
     With these  assumptions in mind, the fed cattle industry employes  either
     full-time or part-time the estimated following amounts of people:
    
                                 Number of      Av. per     Estimated  Number
     Size of Feedlot Capacity       Feedlots      Feedlot     of People Employed
         1,000 Head                152,429         1.0            152,500
         1,000 -  1,999                912         1.8              1,600
         2,000-  3,999                484         3.5              1,700
         4,000 -  7,999                311         7. 1              2,200
         8,000 - 15,999                216        12.0              2,600
        16,000-31,999                125       24.0              3,000
        32,000 or more             	5J9_      45.8              2,700
              Total                154,536         1.1            166,300
    
                                      11-17
    

    -------
               C.  Relationship of Segments to Total Industry
    
    Number of Production Units
    
    Iowa leads the  United States  in the number of feedlots followed by
    Nebraska, Illinois and Minnesota.  These four states account for forty-
    eight percent of the  total number of feedlots  in the  United States.
                                                              Percent of all
        State                     Number of Feedlots         U.S. Feedlots
    
        Iowa            '                36,000                     23.1
        Nebraska                       17, 172                      11. 1
        Illinois                         16,500                      10.7
        Minnesota                      14,000                       9.1
        Kansas                           7,500                       4.8
        Texas                            1.530                       1.0
        Colorado                           812                       0.5
        Oklahoma                          500                       0.3
        California                          308                       0.2
        Arizona                           •  53
                                         94,375                     61.1
    
     The above ten states  account for sixty-one percent of all the United
     States' feedlots, and  market eighty-four percent of all fed cattle.  The
     majority of  these states' feedlots (98 percent) are farmer feeders with
     feedlot capacity less  than 1,000 head.  Of the ten leading states,  all but
     California and Arizona have the majority of their feedlots with less than
     1,000 head  capacity  (Table II-9).  However, in the past ten years, there
     has been a decreasing number of farmer feeders in all states.
    
     Farmer feeders are predominately located in the Corn Belt States while
     the Southwestern states have shown indications of moving toward more
     commercial operations. Since 1962, Arizona, Oklahoma, and California
     have had the most  significant decreases in the number of farmer feeders;
     Arizona decreased by 92.6 percent,  Oklahoma by 78.7 percent, and
     California by 69.2 percent (Table 11-10). All these  exits have occurred
     during a time when fed  cattle marketings have increased.  Thus,  the trend
     has been for several  small farmer feeders to leave the industry being
     replaced by a larger  commercial feedlot whose  capacity exceeds that of
     the combined total of the farmer feeders leaving.
                                   11-18
    

    -------
    Table II-9.  Number of feedlots and cattle marketed by size, ten leading states, 1972
    
    Texas
    No. feedlots
    Cattle mkt.
    Number (1,000)
    Percent
    Nebraska
    No. feedlots
    Cattle mkt.
    Number (1,000)
    Percent
    H
    ,!_ Iowa
    No. feedlots
    Cattle mkt.
    Number (1,000)
    Percent
    Kansas
    No. feedlots
    Cattle mkt.
    Number (1,000)
    Percent
    Colorado
    No. feedlots
    Cattle mkt.
    Number (1,000)
    Percent
    1,000
    
    1,300
    
    98
    2.3
    
    16,629
    
    1,615
    40.5
    
    
    35,830
    
    3,556
    89.2
    
    7,369
    
    489
    20.3
    
    621
    
    183
    8.0
    1,000-
    1,999
    
    53
    
    57
    1.3
    
    305
    
    505
    12.6
    
    
    89
    
    140
    3.5
    
    36
    
    52
    2.2
    
    67
    
    118
    5.2
    2,000-
    3,999
    
    38
    
    112
    2.6
    
    140
    
    510
    12.8
    
    
    56
    
    135
    3.4
    
    17
    
    55
    2.3
    
    49
    
    163
    7. 1
    4,000-
    7,999
    
    39
    
    308
    7. 1
    
    66
    
    510
    12.8
    
    
    19
    
    90
    2.3
    
    26
    
    241
    10.0
    
    36
    
    299
    13. 1
    8,000-
    15,999
    
    38
    
    558
    13.0
    
    20
    
    345
    8.6
    
    
    6
    
    65
    1.6
    
    31
    
    580
    24. 1
    
    23
    
    439
    19.2
    16,000-
    31,999
    
    38
    
    1,420
    33.0
    
    8
    
    270
    6.8
    
    
    --
    
    --
    
    
    16
    
    637
    26.5
    
    11
    
    360
    15.7
    32,000
    or more
    
    24
    
    1,755
    40.7
    
    4
    
    235
    5.9
    
    
    --
    
    --
    
    
    5
    
    351
    14.6
    
    5
    
    729
    31.8
    Total
    
    1,530
    
    4,308
    100
    
    17, 172
    
    3,990
    100
    
    
    36,000
    
    3,986
    100
    
    7,500
    
    2,405
    100
    
    812
    
    2,291
    100
    

    -------
                                              Table II-9.  (continued)
    
    California
    No. feedlots
    Cattle mkt.
    Number (1,000)
    Percent
    Illinois
    No. feedlots
    Cattle mkt.
    Number (1,000)
    Percent
    i— i
    V Minnesota
    o No. feedlots
    Cattle mkt.
    Number (1,000)
    Percent
    Arizona
    No. feedlots
    Cattle mkt.
    Number (1,000)
    Percent
    Oklahoma
    No. feedlots
    Cattle mkt.
    Number (1,000)
    Percent
    1,000
    
    94
    
    8
    0.4
    
    16,440
    
    886
    88.3
    
    13,965
    
    883
    94.4
    
    7
    
    2
    0.2
    
    459
    
    47
    7.5
    1,000-
    1,999
    
    42
    
    23
    1. 1
    
    49
    
    65
    6.5
    
    29
    
    37
    4.0
    
    5
    
    5
    0.6
    
    8
    
    12
    1.9
    2,000-
    3,999
    
    51
    
    47
    2.3
    
    6
    
    19
    1.9
    
    6
    
    15
    1.6
    
    7
    
    18
    2.0
    
    9
    
    35
    5.6
    4,000- 8,000- 16,000- 32,000
    7,999 15,999 31,999 or more
    
    45 43 23 10
    
    227 526 625 606
    11.0 25.5 30.3 29.4
    
    5
    
    33*
    3.3
    
    --
    
    __
    
    
    8899
    
    43 120 210 501
    4.8 13.3 23.4 55.7
    
    7 11 6
    
    92 145 295*
    14.7 23.2 47.1
    Total
    
    308
    
    2,062
    100
    
    16,500
    
    1,003
    100
    
    14,000
    
    935
    100
    
    53
    
    • 899
    100
    
    500
    
    626
    100
    Source:  Cattle on Feed,  USDA,  SRS
    .I/ Lots and marketings from larger size groups are included to avoid disclosing individual operations.
    

    -------
         Table 11-10. Percentage change in number of feedlots, by size,  1962 to 1972, for the ten leading states
    State
    Texas
    Nebraska
    Iowa
    Kansas
    Colorado
    California
    Illinois
    Minnesota
    Arizona
    Oklahoma
    Less
    than
    1,000
    -18.7
    -30.6
    -28.3
    -50.7
    -48.7
    -69.2
    -48.6
    -41.7
    -92.6
    -78.7
    Percentage Change
    1,000-
    1,999
    -45.9
    50.9
    169.7
    50.0
    116. 1
    -60.4
    133.3
    70.6
    -83.3
    -38.4
    2,000-
    3,999
    -36.7
    86.7
    1,766.7
    112.5
    157.8
    -49.0
    (6)
    50.0
    -72.0
    -0. 1
    4,000-
    7,999
    25.8
    75.0
    (19)
    116.7
    125.0
    9.7
    66.7
    --
    -61.9
    16.7
    8,000-
    15,999
    71.4
    81.8
    (6)
    244.4
    64.3
    16.2
    
    
    -27.2
    (11)
    16,000-
    31,999
    (38)
    (8)
    
    (16)
    (11)
    76.9
    
    
    28.6
    (6)
    32,000
    and over
    (24)
    (4)
    
    (5)
    (5)
    233.3
    
    
    (9)
    
    Total
    -15. 1
    -29.3
    -28.0
    -50.0
    -36.6
    -49. 1
    -48.4
    -41.6
    -72.0
    -77.0
    Source:  Cattle on Feed, USDA, SRS
    Note: Parenthesis denote an increase from zero to the number in the parenthesis.
    

    -------
    The majority of these commercial feedlots tend to be concentrating in the
    Great Plains and the Southwestern States.  Arizona, California and Texas
    have all had significant increases in the number of feedlots with capacity
    of 32, 000 or more head with Kansas, Colorado, California,  and Texas
    showing major increases in feedlots with capacity between 16, 000 and
    31, 999 head.  Recent trends have indicated that this shift will continue
    to move in the  same direction.
    
    Production
    
    Marketings of fed cattle are highly concentrated, with the ten principal
    states marketing nearly eighty-four  percent of all fed cattle marketed.
    The three leading states, Texas,  Nebraska, and Iowa,  contributed over
    forty-five percent of all marketings.  The  following four states, Kansas,
    Colorado,  California, and Illinois added another thirty percent to make
    the seven leading states supplying nearly seventy-five percent of all fed
    cattle marketings.   With the exception of California, Texas  and Arizona,
    the leading ten states are located in  the western Corn Belt and Northern
    Plains.
                                     1972
                               Cattle Marketed          Percent of
        State                    JJ^00 Head)        JJ. S. JMarjceUngs
    
        Te:ias                      4, 308                  16.  1
        Nebraska                   3,990                  14.9
        Iowa                        3,986                  14.8
        Kansas                     Z,405                   9.0
        Colorado                   2,291                   8.5
        California                  2,062                   7.7
        Illinois                     1,003                   3.7
        Minnesota                    935                   3.5
        Arizona                       899                   3.3
        Oklahoma                     626                   2.3
                                   22, 505                  83.9
     The recent increases in number of fed cattle marketings have been
     concentrated in the southern Corn Belt, Northern Plains and the South-
     western States.   These states have all more than doubled the number
     of marketings since 1962 (Table 11-11). Some of the traditional pro-
     ducing states such as California and Iowa have had  only slight increases
     in marketings and Illinois actually had a decrease.
                                     11-22
    

    -------
     Table 11-11. Changes in number of fed cattle marketed, ranked by
                           1972 marketings, 23 states.
    Number of Head
    State
    
    Texas
    Nebraska
    Iowa
    Kansas
    Colorado
    California
    Illinois
    Minnesota
    Arizona
    Oklahoma
    Missouri
    South Dakota
    Indiana
    Ohio
    Idaho
    New Mexico
    Washington
    Michigan
    Montana
    Wisconsin
    Oregon
    Pennsylvania
    North Dakota
    23 State Total
    1962
    
    756
    1 , 822
    2,687
    774
    815
    1,844
    1,265
    609
    568
    186
    542
    451
    355
    376
    221
    129
    258
    208
    100
    168
    148
    142
    136
    14, 560
    1972
    --1,000 head--
    4,308
    3,990
    3,936
    2,405
    2,291
    2,062
    1,003
    935
    899
    626
    604
    561
    478
    438
    428
    376
    275
    251
    247
    214
    143
    130
    85
    26, 835
    Percent
    Change
    
    470
    119
    48
    211
    181
    12
    -11
    54
    58
    237
    11
    24
    35
    16
    94
    191
    45
    21
    147
    27
    _ 3
    - 8
    -37
    84
    Source:  Cattle on Feed,  U. S. D. A. , S. R. S.
                                  11-23
    

    -------
                                           Change in Production
                       State                     1962 to 1972
                                                 (Percent)
                       Texas                       470
                       Oklahoma                   237
                       Kansas                      211
                       New Mexico                 191
                       Colorado                    181
                       Montana                     147
                       Nebraska                   119
                       Idaho     '                     94
                       Arizona                       58
                       Minnesota                     54
                       Iowa                          48
                       California                     12
                       Illinois                      -1 1
    
    Cattle feeding tends to be moving vVest.  Increases in feed grain pro-
    duction in Kansas,  Oklahoma and Colorado, coupled with increasing land
    prices in the Eastern Corn Belt have helped drive these cattle west.
    Also as larger feedlots are developed, the drier climate offered in the
    Great  Plains and the Southwest has made that area much more desirable
    as a location for large-scale cattle feedlots.
    
    Employment
    
    Labor requirements for beef feedlot operators are dependent on two
    principle factors:  ( 1) the size of the operation; and (2) the degree to
    which  the operation is mechanized. In most cases,  the  degree of
    mechanization is dependent on the size of the  operation.
     The large commercial feedlot usually is highly mechanized in order to
     gain optimum efficiency for each hired man used.  As feedlots increase
     in size there appears to be a stair-step increase in both employment and
     mechanization.  That is, as a feedlot increases from 10,000 head capacity
     to 12,000 head only additional labor is  required, however, when the
     feedlot increases from 10,000 to 20,000 head some labor may be added
     but also new larger, labor saving machinery will be added.
    
     The farmer feeder's feedlot is commonly a family operation.  The
     farmer feeds cattle to supplement his  farm income.  He usually does
     not have a highly mechanized operation and the size of the operation is
     often dependent on the amount of extra  time the farmer has and to what
                                   11-24
    

    -------
    extent he can use his family (for example his wife and/or sons).  Approxi-
    mately 152,500 people are employed either part or full time on farmer-
    feeder operations.  Commercial feedlots employ approximately another
    14, 000 people who are predominately full time hired  laborers.
                                    11-25
    

    -------
               II.  FED CATTLE INDUSTRY FINANCIAL PROFILE
    The focal point of this financial analysis is the producer who feeds beef
    cattle in a confinement or semi-confinement system.   Cattle are fattened
    on feed grains and concentrates with limited pasture.  Feedlots generally
    are based upon a lot system with animal density ranging from 50 square
    feet per head to about 400 square feet.  Cost data used was  derived from
    several sources; however,  two sources were of particular usefulness. L'
                             A.  Plants by Segments
    Financial profiles were developed for six feedlot operations varying in
    size and level of technology.  The two smallest feedlots--those with
    capacities of 100 and 500 head—are generally owned by farmer feeders.
    These  involve relatively low capital investment and are labor intensive
    operations.   The other feedlots analyzed—those with capacities of 1,000,
    5, 000,  10, 000 and 20, 000 head—are considered to be commercial feedlot
    operations.   These larger lots usually have high capital investment require-
    ments  and utilize new technological practices.
    
    The farmer feeder uses  his feedlot as a source of supplemental income.
    He often has other farm  enterprises and typically feeds cattle out only once
    a year.  The commercial operator usually  feeds cattle throughout the  year.
    The commercial operator purchases most of his inputs from outside sources
    and may be  dependent on the feedlot as a primary source of income.
    
    Costs developed for  the six model feedlots  attempt to represent typical
    cattle feeding operations in the  United States. We realize, however,  that
    there may be some regional variations in costs.
    
    Annual Profits before Taxes
    
    Based  on the model  operations procedures  and assumptions,  the  estimated
    annual pre-tax incomes for the  various sized feedlots ranged from $1,600
    for the  100 head feedlot to $545, 100 for the feedlot with a capacity of
    20,000 cattle (Table 11-12).
    y
       Various farm management Extension Bulletins from Iowa State University
       and "The Arizona Cattle Feeding Industry," Russell Gum and Elmer
       Menzie,  Tech. Bull. 191, Uriv. of Arizona, Jan., 1972.
                                     11-26
    

    -------
           Table 11-12.   Estimated pre-tax income and rate of return on average invested capital
    
                            and after-tax  return on sales for various sized cattle feedlots
    Financial Measure
    Pre-tax net income ($000)
    Pre-tax ROI* (%)
    After-tax ROI* (%)
    After-tax return on sales (%)
    Capacity
    100 500 1,000
    1.6 5.2 35.3
    28.9 15.5 39-2
    22.5 12.1 27.6
    4.0 2.6 3.7
    - Number Head
    5,000 . 10,000
    82.7 232.6
    17.3 28.0
    10.4 15.4
    1.5 2.5
    
    20,000
    545. 1
    35.8
    19-0
    2.2
    -'
    'LI Average return on fixed investment calculated by financial statement method.
    

    -------
    Differences between the various feedlot's rates of return on investment
    both before and after taxes is primarily due to different levels of invest-
    ment required.   The small farmer feeder has relatively little invested
    in fixed facilities.   Besides the fenced lot and home-made feed bunks,
    the farmer feeder can utilize equipment already on the farm to feed his  cattle.
    The 1, 000 head capacity feedlot usually requires a small feed mill which,
    with 1, 000 head on feed, simplifies the operation.  As feedlots increase
    in size beyond the 1, 000 head capacity, higher capital investments are
    required but economics of scale occur as the facilities and equipment are
    more fully utilized.
    
    Book value of assets, on which  the rates of return were calculated,
    were derived by dividing replacement costs by two;  plus net working
    capital (current assets  less current liabilities).  The average fixed
    investment value is  intended to  approximate invested capital.
    
    Profitability of cattle feedlots is dependent upon price  of feed  grains,  the
    price of feeder cattle, and the price received for sale  of slaughter- cattle.
    Changes  in these factors significantly change the profitablility of feeding
    cattle.
    
    Annual Cash Flow
    
    Estimated annual cash flow  is calculated by adding depreciation charges to
    after-tax  net income.   The percentage cash flow on average fixed invest-
    ment and  the annual cash flow for various sized lots are shown in Table
    11-13 and  Table  11-14.   Depreciation was computed using industry guide-
    lines for both facilities and  equipment.
    
    The annual cash flow varied from $1, 500 for the smallest  model feedlot
    to $374,400 for  the 20, 000 head capacity feedlot.  Cash flow as a percent
    of average investment varied especially for the three  smaller feedlots.
    For feedlots with capacities of 5, 000 head  or more, the percentage in-
    creased as size increased.  This is explained by variations in investment
    required for the various sized operations which was explained previously.
    
    Market (Salvage) Value of Assets
    
    The facilities involved with  feeding cattle are somewhat limited as to
    their usefulness in other farm enterprises.  The small farmer feeder
    may be able to use some of his  facilities in connection with other enter-
    prises, however,  most of the facilities can only be adapted to a large
    animal enterprise.  The commercial feeder has relatively no  alternative
    use for his feedlot facilities. Because of this, the salvage value of assets
    for cattle feedlots is assumed to be not more than ten percent of replace-
    ment value.
    
                                    11-28
    

    -------
    NO
                          Table 11-13.   Estimated caih flow for various sized cattle feedlots
              Financial Measure
     100
    500
                                                                        Capacity  - Number Head
    1,000      5,000
               10,000
               20,000
              Annual cash flow ($000)
     1. 5
    7. 1
     30. 3
    75, 1
    163.9
    347.4
              Cash flow on average fixed
                investment (%)
    28.5     21.3
              33.6
               15.7
                 19. 8
                                                                                                           22. 8
    

    -------
                            Table 11-14. Estimated cash flow for various sized cattle feedlots.
    UJ
    o
    
    
    Utilization (Turns per year)
    Annual Output (No. head marketed)
    Sale si/ 30
    Less Variable Expense:
    Steers 20
    Feed 7
    Othe r 1
    Less Fixed Expense
    Cash Earnings 1
    Less Depreciation
    Less Interest
    Pre-Tax Income
    Excluding Family Income
    Cash Earnings 2
    Less Depreciation
    Less Interest
    Pre-Tax Income 1
    
    100
    1.0
    100
    ,745
    
    , 100
    ,400
    ,479
    65
    ,701
    324
    683
    694
    
    ,565
    324
    683
    ,558
    
    500
    1. 0
    500
    153,725
    
    100,500
    37, 000
    4,938
    670
    10,617
    3,078
    3,806
    3,733
    
    12,080
    3,078
    3,806
    5, 196
    Capacity -
    1, 000
    2. 16
    2, 160
    664,092
    
    434, 160
    159,840
    18,804
    1,296
    49,992
    5,400
    13, 157
    31,435
    
    53,892
    5,400
    13, 157
    35,335
    Number Head
    5,000
    2. 16
    10,800
    3,320,460
    
    2, 170,800
    840,456
    116,532
    17,280
    175,392
    25,596
    67,080
    82,716
    
    
    
    
    
    10,000
    2. 16
    21,600
    6,640,920
    
    4,341, 600
    1,680,912
    191, 160
    31,320
    395,928
    36,504
    126,840
    232,584
    
    
    
    
    
    20,000
    2. 16
    43,200
    13,281,840
    
    8,683,200
    3,361,824
    341,280
    47,093
    848,443
    57,456
    245,880
    545, 107
    
    
    
    
    
            - $307. 45 per head = 10 cwt.  X . 96 shrink adjustment X . 99 death loss adjustment X $32. 35/cwt.
    

    -------
    Capital Structure
    
    It is assumed that entry into the beef feeding industry is relatively easy
    for small operations, in that only moderate amounts  of capital are
    necessary to build the required facilities (Table 11-15).  As capacity of
    feedlots increases,  so does capital requirement.  A small feedlot with
    capacity of 100 cattle requires an estimated $6, 000 for facilities.  In
    comparison, a feedlot with capacity of 20, 000 cattle requires an estimated
    $960, 000 for facilities and equipment.
    
    Working capital requirements are also directly related to the size of the
    operation.
    
    Cost Structure
    
    Model cattle feedlot data and budgets were  prepared to estimate the cost
    structure of representative  operations. Costs were classified into two
    categories--fixed and variable (Table 11-16).  Since  it was assumed that
    feedlots would purchase feeder cattle from outside sources, the cost of
    feeder cattle was the most significant cost  incurred.   Feed was the second
    most significant cost.
    
    Variable costs made up more than 90 percent of sales for all model feedlots
    (Table 11-17).  Total cost, as a percent of  sales ranged between 95 and 98
    percent for all the model  feedlots.
                      B.  Ability to Finance New Investments
    Cattle feeders,  in the past, have relied upon the Production Credit Asso-
    ciation,  Farmers Home Administration and particularly private financial
    institutions as sources of financing for new  investments.   The relatively
    high cash flow and good profitability of feeding cattle has provided the
    financial help required by most cattle feedlots.  Therefore,  it is doubtful
    if feedlot operators will encounter any difficulty in obtaining additional
    financing for their feedlot operations.  Cattle feeding is one of the more
    glamorous farm enterprises.
                                      11-31
    

    -------
    Table II- 15,   Estimated replacement value and working capital requirements for various sized
                                             cattle feedlots.
    
    
                                                            Capacity - Number Head
        Capital Component
                                       100       500     1,000    5,000       10,000	20,000
    
    Replacement value o£ facilities
        and equipment ($000)           6.0      43.1     76.8     427.0        610.0       960.0
    
    Net working capital ($000)          12.2      60. 1    258.0    1,320.9      2,622.9     5,222.0
    
    Replacement value of total
        assets ($000)                  18.2     103.2    334.8    1,747.9      3,232.9     6,182.0
    

    -------
                           Table  II-16. Total investment and annual cost for various sized cattle feedlots,
                                                    Iowa and Arizona, 1971
    I
    LO
    Capacity - Numoer Head
    
    Total Investment
    Annual Fixed Costs
    Insurance & Taxes
    Interest on Investment
    Management
    Depreciation-
    Total FixedCosts
    Annual Variable Costs
    Steers
    Feed
    Labor (hired)
    Vet & Medical
    Taxes (Cattle)
    Interest (Cattle
    Other
    Family Labor
    Total Variable Costs
    Total Costs
    Total Costs Excluding
    Family Labor
    100
    $6,000
    
    65
    180
    -
    324
    569
    
    20, 100
    7,400
    -
    255
    100
    50
    260
    864
    29,482
    30,051
    
    29, 187
    500
    $43,092
    
    670
    1 , 293
    -
    3,078
    5,041
    
    100, 500
    37,000
    -
    1,000
    500
    2,513
    1,975
    1,463
    144,951
    149,992
    
    148,529
    1,000
    $76,780
    
    1,296
    2,303
    -
    5,400
    8,999
    
    434, 160
    159,840
    -
    4,104
    2, 160
    10,854
    8,640
    3,900
    623,658
    632,657
    
    628,757
    5,000
    $427,000
    
    6,264
    12,810
    11,016
    25,596
    55,686
    
    2, 170,800
    840,456
    58, 320
    18,792
    10, 800
    54, 270
    28,620
    -
    3, 182,058
    3, 237,744
    
    
    10,000
    S610, 000
    
    9,288
    18,300
    22,032
    36,504
    86, 124
    
    4, 341,600
    1, 680,912
    87,480
    37, 584
    21 .. 600
    108, 540
    44,496
    -
    6,322,212
    6,408, 336
    
    
    20,000
    $960,000
    
    14,261
    28,800
    32, 832
    57,456
    133, 349
    
    8,683, 200
    3,361, 824
    150, 336
    75, 168
    43,200
    217,080
    72, 576
    -
    12,603,384
    12,736,733
    
    
       I/ Depreciation rate for feedlots under 5,000 head capacity was 7 percent,  for those with capacity of 5,000 or over ,
          6 percent was used.
       Assumptions:
          -Cost were calculated for the 100, 500 and 1 , 000 head feedlots from various Farm Management Extension Bulletins
           from Iowa State University.
          -Cost were calculated for the 5,000, 10,000 and 20,000 head feedlots from: "The Arizona Cattle Feeding  Industry,"
           Russell Gum and Elmer L. Menzie, Tech. Bull.  191,  Univ. of Arizona, Jan.  1972.
          -All Cost were inflated to present 1971 cost
          -Cost were calculated based on a 2. 16  capacity turnover rate for all feedlots except tnose with 100 and 500
           head capacity which were assumed to  feed only once a year.
    

    -------
                                  Table 11-17.  Estimated costs for various  sized cattle feedlots
    
    Capacity - Number Head
    Item
    
    Sales
    Raw materials:
    Steers
    Raw materials:
    Feed
    Other variable
    costs
    Fixed costs
    Depreciation
    Interest
    Total before-
    100
    $000
    30.7
    20. 1
    
    7.4
    
    1. 5
    
    . 1
    . 3
    .7
    30. 1
    
    %
    100.
    65.
    
    24.
    
    4.
    
    •
    1.
    2.
    98.
    
    
    0
    5
    
    1
    
    9
    
    3
    0
    3
    0
    500
    $000
    153. 7
    100. 5
    
    37. 0
    
    4.9
    
    . 7
    3. 1
    3. 8
    150.0
    
    
    1
    ,000
    % $000 %
    100.
    65.
    
    24.
    
    3.
    
    
    2.
    2.
    97.
    0
    4
    
    1
    
    2
    
    5
    0
    5
    6
    664.
    434.
    
    159-
    
    18.
    
    1.
    5.
    13.
    632.
    1
    2
    
    8
    
    8
    
    3
    4
    2
    7
    100. 0
    65.4
    
    24. 1
    
    2. 8
    
    . 2
    . 8
    2. 0
    95.3
    5,
    $000
    3,320.
    2,170.
    
    840.
    
    116.
    
    17.
    25.
    67.
    3,237.
    000
    %
    5 100.0
    8 65.4
    
    5 25. 3
    
    5 3. 5
    
    3 . 5
    6 .8
    1 2. 0
    8 97. 5
    1
    $000
    6,640.
    4,341.
    
    1,680.
    
    191.
    
    31.
    36.
    126.
    6,408.
    0,
    
    9
    6
    
    9
    
    2
    
    3
    5
    8
    3
    000
    %
    100.0
    65.4
    
    25. 3
    
    2.9
    
    . 5
    . 5
    1.9
    96.5
    20,000
    $000
    13, 281.
    8,683.
    
    3,361.
    
    341.
    
    47.
    57.
    245.
    12,736.
    
    8
    2
    
    8
    
    3
    
    1
    5
    9
    8
    %
    100. 0
    65.4
    
    25. 3
    
    2.6
    
    .4
    .4
    1-9
    95.9
    tax cost
    

    -------
                     PART III:  THE HOG INDUSTRY
    
    
                     I.  HOG INDUSTRY SEGMENTS
    
    
                           A.   Types of Firms
    An examination of the different livestock enterprises shows that the hog
    enterprise is one that is adaptable to many situations.  It can be operated
    with a wide range  of systems and equipment,  according to the  capital and
    labor provided by  the owner.  In general,  it shows a good  return of the
    feed fed, has a high rate of capital turnover,  and is very responsive to
    good management  practices. —'
    
    The United States  hog industry consisted of 810,400 producers in 1972.
    These operations may range from less than ten head to several thousand
    head.  In 1969, sixty-eight percent of all the producers had less than 100
    head.  These operations accounted for only 22 percent  of the hogs on hand.
    The  remaining 78  percent of the hogs  on hand were on farms of 100 head
    or more.  This emphasizes a recent trend toward fewer hog producers
    with those  remaining expanding their operations.
    
    Number and Size of Producing Units
    
    The United States  hog industry in 1972 included 810,400 producers com-
    pared with nearly  two million in I960 and slightly more than three million
    in 1950.  This decline  continued in the sixties, declining from 1,057,570
    producers  in 1965  to 810,400 in 1972, a decline of 23 percent.
    
                             Number of farms              Index
    Year                       with hogs -'               1965 = 100
    1965                        1,057,570                   100.0
    1966                        1,055,950                    99.8
    1967                        1,042,140                    98.5
    1968                          967,580                    91.5
    1969                          873,840                    82.6
    1970                          875,480                    82.8
    1971                          879,980                    83.2
    1972                          810,400                    76.6
    —  "Pork Production on a Business Basis," Department of Economics,
       Cooperative Extension Service,  Kansas State University, October, 1970.
    —  Number of farms with hogs as reported by SRS, USDA, includes all farms
       with hogs.  Number of farms reported exceeds that total reported by 1969
       Census of Agriculture. Differences are a result of the Census including
       only farms with gross incomes of $2, 500 or more.
                                   III-l
    

    -------
    During the period from 1969 to  1971 there was a slight increase in the
    number of hog producers.   This, in part,  can be explained by the  ease
    of entry into the hog business.  Entry into the feeder pig or slaughter
    hog business has few restrictions except for extremely large commercial
    operations that have large  capital requirements.  Producer entry  and exit
    from the hog business is still closely  related to current hog prices.
    When market hog prices reach a relatively high profit level for a sus-
    tained period, new  producers enter the hog business. Others delay  their
    decision to quit the business and many increase production.  The opposite
    occurs when hog prices decline  for a sustained period of time.
    
    This reaction to prices causes the  hog business to be cyclic in nature.
    However,  fewer producers  are  entering the hog business with each upturn
    in cycle.  This is due to the general emphasis by farmers on specialization.
    Farmers  are now becoming more specialized and on many farms the hog
    business has been eliminated.   Thus,  the farmers remaining in the  hog in-
    dustry are generally producing  more hogs with hog production becoming a
    primary enterprise.
    
    Since 1964, the number of farms with ZOO head or more of hogs  on hand
    has increased (Table III-l). Farms with ZOO to 499 head increased  16
    percent, those with 500-999 head increased 73 percent, and those farms
    with 1,000 or more head increased by 116 percent.  The exit from the
    industry of the  smaller producers is somewhat misleading due to the fact
    that in 1964 the Agricultural Census included all farms while in 1969, only
    farms with gross sales of $2,500 or more were counted.  Many of the farms
    eliminated in 1969 would be the typical part-time farmer that might have
    a few head of hogs.
    
    Volume of Marketings
    
    Total hog marketings  in 1971 included nearly 99 million head.  This ac-
    counted for over 23 billion  pounds of pork and provided  cash receipts of
    over four billion dollars.  The year 1971 represented an increase of
    23 percent during the past ten years,  in the number of head marketed
    (Table III-2).
    
    Basically the majority of hogs are concentrated on farms with inventories
    ranging from 100 - 499 head.  Twenty-nine percent of all farms with hogs
    were  in this classification  in 1969 and controlled 57 percent of all hogs.
                                   IH-2
    

    -------
        Table IH-1. Number of farms with hogs, by size and percent of hogs
                       on hand, 1964 and 1969, 48 states, U.S.
    1 / ?/
    1964- 1969^
    Size Number
    Farms
    < 10 448,942
    10 - 24 186,778
    25 - 99 276,099
    100 - 199 106,449
    200 - 499 54,550
    500 - 999 6,421
    1,000 or more 1 , 132
    Total 1,080,371
    Percent Percent
    of Hogs on Number
    Farms Hand Farms
    41.5 3.0 89,789
    17.3 5.4 85,306
    25.6 26.6 187,682
    9-9 26.4 92,939
    5.0 28.0 63,014
    0.6 7.4 11,119
    0.1 3.2 2,443
    100.0 100.0 532,292
    Percent Percent
    of Hogs— on
    Farms Hand
    16-9 0.8
    16.0 2.6
    35.2 19-0
    17.5 23.7
    11.8 33.7
    2.1 13.2
    0. 5 7. 0
    100.0 100.0
    Source:  \J Census of Agriculture,  1964.  Includes all Farms
    
            —  Census of Agriculture,  1969.  Farms with gross sales  of $2,500
               or more.
            _' Percent  of all hogs.
                                  III-3
    

    -------
           Table III-2. Hog marketings and cash receipts, 1961-1972
    Year
    1961
    1962
    1963
    1964
    1965
    1966
    1967
    1968
    1969
    1970
    1971
    
    Marketings.1./
    1,000 Head 1, 000 Pounds
    80,326
    81,743
    86, 163
    86,086
    76,079
    76,504
    84,995
    87,907
    88, 335
    87, 143
    98,636
    18, 917,418
    19,310,335
    20, 273, 936
    20,487,965
    17, 921,484
    17,965,389
    19,886,322
    ?C. 423, 394
    20,717,424
    20, 412,457
    23, 154, 109
    Cash Receipts^'
    1, 000 Dollars
    •
    3, 152, 383
    3, 161, 521
    3,033,284
    3, 033, 518
    3,693, 341
    4,093, 016
    3,754,775
    3,784,781
    4,589, 070
    4,634, 488
    4, 047,277
    J:' Excludes inter-farm sales.
    
    
    
    2/ Receipts from Marketings and from sales of farm slaughter meats.
    
    
    
    Source:  Livestock and Meat Situation, USDA,  SRS.
                                   III-4
    

    -------
                                     Percent of Hogs on Hand
    Nnmtx
    
    
    
    
    
    
    1.
    <
    10
    25
    100
    200
    500
    000
    sr of Head per Farm
    ' 10
    - 24
    - 99
    - 199
    - 499
    - 999
    or more
    1964
    3.0
    5.4
    26.6
    26.4
    28.0
    7.4
    3.2
    1969
    0.8
    2.6
    19.0
    23.7
    33.7
    13.2
    7.0
    Age of Production Facilities
    
    Information available pertaining to the age of hog production facilities is
    somewhat limited.   Because of this, it is assumed that the age of facilities
    is related to the  growth of production.  This is a  reasonable assumption
    for a larger modern production operation.  However, for the smaller
    producer, it will be difficult to determine the age of his facilities since
    often, he uses equipment and facilities that have been adapted for hogs
    from other enterprises.
    
    Using the assumption stated, states such as Kansas, Nebraska, Missouri,
    South Dakota and Iowa, which have had significant increases in hog mar-
    ketings, •will tend to have newer facilities.
    
    Also it should be assumed that the larger hog operations require more
    capital investment than a small operation, so it would  seem  likely that
    the large operator would tend to keep his investment updated.  Therefore
    there would be a  tendency for the larger operations to  have  newer equipment
    and facilities.
    
    Location of Major Producing Segments
    
    Hog production is concentrated in the Corn  Belt area of the  United States.
    Current trends suggest that this area will remain the principal production
    center.  The ten  major Corn Belt states (Ohio, Indiana,  Illinois, Wisconsin,
    Minnesota, Iowa, Missouri, South Dakota,  Nebraska,  and Kansas) have
    produced about 75 percent of the total  pig crop for the  past twenty years.
    Hog production also has some  sign'ficant emphasis  in the South Central
    and South Atlantic regions -- each of which accounts for about ten percent
    of the total United States pig crop.
                                   Ill-5
    

    -------
    Level of Technology
    
    The technological level of pork producers depends, to a degree, upon
    the size of the operation. In many cases, the small operation uses
    low levels  of available technology while the large operation uses the
    latest methods available.
    
    Hog producers have a variety of management systems that can be  util-
    ized (Table III-3).  These may range from breeding sows and feeding
    pigs up to market weight to buying small pigs and feeding these to
    ma rket weight.  The type of management system has some relationship
    with the number of hogs handled,  especially for  the large operator.
    The small  operator may have any combination of systems, some small
    operators will have a sow or two and raise its pigs while  other small
    operators may buy a few feeder pigs and fatten these out.  The larger
    operator may lean more toward the farrow-to-finish operation in an
    effort to assure  himself a good supply of feeder  pigs.
    
    The farrow-to-finish operation is the most common system among hog
    producers.  It accounts for over 45 percent of the  hog operators and
    supplies  nearly  sixty percent of the market hogs sold.  The farrow-to-
    finish operation also accounts for nearly 58 percent of the sows  on hand.
    
    Eleven_percent of the hog farmers raise feeder pigs only. They supply
    54 percent of the feeder pigs sold and have 12 percent of all  sows  on
    hand.  Farmers who buy feeder pigs and feed these until market weight
    account for about  16 percent of all hog farmers.  These operators supply
    18 percent of the market hogs sold.  The remainder of the hog producers
    is made up of various combinations of these three  management systems,
    with exception of the purebred breeder who accounts for only four percent
    of all hog producers (Table III-3).
    
    Unlike the  large producer who has all the necessary equipment, the small
    operators may be dependent on others for some  phase of  their operation.
    Some small pork producers take their home-grown feed  grains to the
    local mill or feed dealer to be ground and have feed additives blended
    in to provide a more balanced hog ration.  This  operator is concerned with
    obtaining more efficient gains so he uses the local feed company to help
    him obtain his desired' gains.
                                    III-6
    

    -------
                  Table III-3.  Inventories and marketings of hogs by management system
    Type of Management System
    Farmers
    Sows
     on
    hand
                                                                               Percent
                                                                          Market
    Hogs
    Sold
    Feeder
     Pigs
     Sold
     Feeder
       Pigs
    Marketed
    Far row-to-finish
    (Finish all pigs farrowed, buy no
    feeder pigs)
    
    Feeder pig producer
    (Finish no pigs,  sell feeders only)
    
    Market hogs only
    (Farrow  no pigs,  buy all feeders)
    
    Far row-finish-pur chase
    (Finish some pigs farrowed,
    and buys feeder pigs too)
    
    Farrow-finish-feeder pig producer
    (Finish some pigs farrowed,  sells feeder
    pigs too)
    
    Purebred breeder
    (Primarily sells breeding stock-
    either  sells or finishes  those left)
       45.6
       11. 1
       15. 5
        9.3
       14.6
        3.9
     57.5     59.7         2.8
     12.0      0.0        53.7
      0.0     18.0         0.1
      9.7     13.3         0.9
     16.8     6.6        41.3
      4.1     2.4         1.2
                                                       0. 0
                                                       0.0
                                                     77.8
                            21.6
                                                       0. 4
                             0.2
      Source:  Unpublished data.  Private sources.
    

    -------
    This small operator will then take his feed back to his farm to be fed
    to his hogs.  Usually he will have less than 50 hogs which may be in
    an open dirt lot or out in the pasture.  The operator may have a  few
    sows,  or may buy feeder pigs from a neighbor.  This operator's hogs
    represent a small portion  of his income so he is willing to put out very
    little additional capital to improve the sophistication of his  hog operation.
    
    In recent years,  this type  of operation has generally given way to a more
    sophisticated hog business in which the operator grows and selects  breeding
    stock from his own herds to provide improved or cross-bred stockfor
    feeding.  This  type of operator  may use one to three or more breeds of
    hogs to develop his desired stock.
    
              Type of Breeding Program Used         Percent of Farmers
    
                    Single Breed                            14
                    Two Breeds                             43
                    Three Breeds                           39
                    Other                                    4
    
    The producers usually perform  most of the  disease, parasite, and sanitary
    control services for his operation.  He also may produce, harvest, mix,
    and grind his own feed grains.  He has achieved a level of knowledge such
    that he can make the majority of the decisions concerning his operation
    himself, thereby eliminating the need to  rely on others for  information.
    
    Many of  the larger operators have operated effectively shifting to more
    intensive capital use.   They have constructed permanent  buildings and
    facilities with more labor-saving equipment.  They arrange confinement
    breeding, farrowing, and feeding operations into one coordinated operation.
    The operators  achieve internal  economies through  better management  to
    control breeding, disease,  feed intake,  environmental factors, and the
    rate of reproduction with multiple farrowing  systems._!/
    
    Level of Efficiency
    
    The efficiency  of hog producers has generally increased in  recent years.
    The effectiveness of a hog operation is usually dependent upon the capa-
    bilities of the operations manager.  Cost  per hog produced  is about the
    same for managers  using high capital technologies as those equally good
    managers not using  these technologies.   The main  reason for operators to
    use slatted floor housing and low-labor feed and waste-handling  systems is
    that good managers  can use their scarce know-how to produce more hogs.
    L' "Coordination in the Corn Belt Pork Industry," E.E.  Broadbent,
         Symposium: Vertical Coordination in the Pork Industry, AVI Publishing
         Company, Inc.
                                   Ill-8
    

    -------
    New labor saving technologies are  enabling swine  producers to double
    numbers of hogs produced with a given labor force.\_' Thus, the use of
    capital has allowed individual producers to handle more hogs and give
    this increased number of hogs the attention necessary for a good pro-
    duction rate.
    
    Level  of Integration
    
    Basically, the open market  directs most of the vertical coordination
    between the production of finished hogs and the slaughter phase.  The
    hog production process can  be divided into five separate stages: (1)
    grain production, (Z) feed milling,  (3) breeding, (4) feeder pig production,
    and (5) hog finishing.  Some hog operations may involve four of the
    production stages, while others may involve  only one,  such as a feeder
    pig operation.
    
    A recent article by Farris and Masch illustrates the direction and possible
    ramifications that characterize vertical coordination within the hog industry.
    They said:
    
            "Many different combinations and variations of control of stages
             are possible  for pork production and marketing.  Much of the
             concern is with  linking feed mills and  packers with stages of
             animal  production by contract or ownership.   Interest is also
             related to the ownership separation  of the feeder pig  and hog-
             finishing stages and coordinating by contract or public market.
             Breeding can also be separated as an independently controlled
             stage.  Because more of these stages  are becoming specialized,
             it is also becoming practical to  separate  and recombine stages
             in different ways.  Furthermore, it is possible to eliminate  a
             stage  -- the public  market for live hogs.   This has important
             implications  not only for market operators, but for the entire
             industry. It  does not mean that an open market will necessarily
             be eliminated, as has essentially been the case for live broilers;
             but it probably means that all but small producers will  be selling
             direct. "2/
    ±J "Management Techniques and Requirements,"  John E. Kadlec,
        Symposium:  Vertical Coordination in the Pork Industry, AVI
        Publishing Company, Inc.
    
    _'  "Vertical Coordination in the Pork Industry in the Southwest," Donald
          E. Farris and William R. Masch, Symposium:  Vertical Coordination
          in the Pork Industry, AVI Publishing Company, Inc.
                                    Ill-9
    

    -------
     Level of Dive rsif-icatiqn
    
     The opportunities facing the majority of the producers in the hog industry
     usually allow producers to quit the hog business without any major con se-
     quences to themselves.  Hogs are used to a large extent by farmers to
    'walk their grain to market'.' Swine producers were primarily cash-crop
     farmers prior to entering the  hog business.  Usually the hog enterprises
     are used in combination with other livestock enterprises such as beef
     cattle or dairy.
    
     If pork producers decide to leave the hog industry they can usually redirect
     their resources  to other livestock enterprises or they may return to cash-
     crop farming.  The latter is especially inviting at the present time with
     the upward trend in grain prices.  Thus, with  the possible exception of capital
     intensive hog operations,  the majority  of swine producers have  alternative
     opportunities to  which they could direct their efforts.
             B.  Number of Plants and Employment by Segments
    
     Of the 810, 400 hog producers reported in 1972, it  is estimated that 99. 5
     percent  of these have operations of less than  1, 000 head.  Predominantly
     these operations are family-owned and the labor used is that labor provided
     by the family.
     The hog operations' labor  requirements often depend on the type of
     management system employed. A farrow-to-finish producer will have
     much different labor requirement than the operators who just buys feeder
     pigs  and feeds them. Under the assumption that modern technologies are
     being used, it is estimated that a  farmer can take care of his own farrow-
     to-finish hog operation  up  to 50 sows.  With more sows  than this,  the
     operator will need to hire  and  extra hand at the  rate of one per additional
     75s ow s.
    
     It is  assumed that producers with 500 hogs on hand or less handle the
     labor requirements  themselves or with some help from  their family.
     For those hog operations with  500 to 1,000 hogs on hand, it is assumed
     that the operator will need to hire an extra man.  For those  hog operations
     of more than 1,000 head, two extra men will be hired.   The  estimated
     total employment by the hog producing industry  involves  employment of
     548,480 people.
                                  Ill-10
    

    -------
             Number of hogs on hand                   Employment
    
                 Less than 500                           518,730
                 500 - 1,000                              22,250
                 More than 1,000                           7 . 500
                 Total                                   548,480
             C.  Relationship of Segments to the Total Industry
    Number of Plants
    
    Iowa leads the United States in the number of farms selling market hogs
    or feeder pigs, followed by Illinois, Missouri,  and Minnesota.  Combined,
    these four states accounted for nearly 40 percent of the total number of
    hog producers in the United States in 1969.
    
                                                            Percent of all U.S.
    gtate                        Number of Farms             Hog Farms	
    
    Iowa                             84,937                       16.0
    Illinois                          46,548                       8.7
    Missouri                         41,828                       7.8
    Minnesota                       36,700                       6.8
    Indiana                          32,003                       6.0
    Nebraska                        29,740                       5.6
    Ohio                             24,789                       4.6
    Wisconsin                       23,495                       4.4
    North Carolina                   19,521                       3.7
    Kentucky                         19,333                       3.6
                                    358,894                       67.2
    
    These  ten leading states account for 67 percent of the total number of
    hogs produced in 1969.  With the exception of North Carolina and Kentucky,
    hogs are concentrated on farms averaging 50 to 500 head each (Table III-4).
    Fifty percent of the hogs in Kentucky and North Carolina are concentrated
    on farms  with less than  50 head.
    
    Looking at the top 20 states in hog production,  there appears to be a
    trend for  those farms  in the Corn Belt states to have medium to large
    hog operations while those farms in the Southern states have small hog
    operations (Appendix III-1).
                                    Ill- 11
    

    -------
               Table III-4, Number of farms  selling market hogs or feeders, ten leading states, by size,  1969
    
    
    
    
    
                  1-9        lcT-49       50-99        100^9         200:-499~"      500-999      1,000+       Total
    State        No.    %    No    %    No,      %   No.      %     No.      %     No.     %    No.    %    No.
    lo^a       1..060   1.2.  8.892   10  5  13..545  15,9 22.. 114  26,0   29,913   35.2   7,960  9.4   1,453  1.8  84,937   100.0
    
    
    
    
    Ilhriois     I..230   "..<-  8,135   17.5   8,755  18.8 I0r822  23,2   12,129   26.1   4,178  9.0   1,299  2.8  46,548   100.0
    
    
    
    
    Missouri   I..430   3,4  9,732   23.3   9,423  22.5 10; 177  24.3    8,639   20.7   1,939  4.6     491  1.2  41,828   100.0
    
    
    
    
    Minnesota  L751   4,8  8,831   24,1   8;602  23.4  8,959  24.4    6,918   18,9   1,370  3,7     269  0.7  36,700   100.0
    
    
    
    
    Indiana       832   2.6  6,007   18,7   6,442  20,1  7,514  23,5    7,891   2407   2,573  8.0     804  2.4  32,003   100.0
    
    
    
    
    
    Nebraska     933   3,1  6,440   21,7   6,752  22,7  7,824  26,3    6,423   21.6   1,124  3.8     244  0.8  29,740   100.0
    
    
    
    
    Ohio       1.210   4,9  6,517   26,3   5,575  22,5  5,398  21.8    4,582   18.5   1,174  4.7     333  1.3  24,789   100.0
    
    
    
    
    
    Wisconsin  1,817   7.7  7,073   30,1   5,166  22,0  5,009  21,3    3,642   15.5     672  2.9     116  0.5  23,495   100.0
    
    
    
    
    N, Carolina2,692  13,8  8,555   43,8   3,553  18,2  2,476  12,7    1,562    8.0     413  2.1     270  1.4  19,521   100.0
    
    
    
    
    Kentucky   1,997  10,3  7,635   39.6   4,261  22.0  3,071  15.9    1,822    9.4     391  2.0     156  0.8  19,333   100.0
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
      Source:   1969 U.S. Census of Agriculture.
    

    -------
     Production
    
     Hog production is concentrated in the Corn Belt states,  with the ten
     major states accounting for 76 percent of hogs marketed within the
     United States.  Iowa is the leading state with 23 percent of all marketings.
     The next three,  Illinois, Missouri and Indiana, added to Iowa, bring the
     percentage of all hog marketings to nearly 50 percent for the first four
     states.
                                                               Percent of all
    State                        Hogs Marketed,  1971          Marketings
                                   (1, 000 head)
    
    Iowa                               22,624                       22.9
    Illinois                            11,569                       11.7
    Missouri                           7,609                        7 7
    Indiana                             7) 124                        7 ?
    Nebraska                           5,952                        6.1
    Minnesota                          5,870                        6.0
    Ohio                                4, 118                        4.2
    Wisconsin                          3_ 422                        3 5
    Kansas                             3,375                        3.4
    South Dakota                        3; 296                        3 3
                                       74,959                     ~Tb7o~
     The Corn Belt states production has grown at a steady rate, as has
     national hog production.  In the past ten years, total marketings  of hogs
     in the U.S. have inc reased by 23.3 pe rcent.   The a ve ra ge numbe r of hogs
     marketed for the ten leading states increased during the  same time period
     by  24.6 percent.  All of the top ten states had  increases  with the greatest
     increases occurring in Kansas and Nebraska (Tablo II1-5).
    
     The majority of hogs marketed are from farms producing 100 to  499
     hogs annually.  In 1969 these farms  marketed  53 percent of all hogs
     (Table III-6).  Farms marketing more than 500 head sold 31 percent
     of all hogs  and  comprised only 6.4 percent of all pro due lion units.
                                     Ill-13
    

    -------
    Table III-5. Trends in hog marketings for the principal ten hog marketing states.
                     Percentage increase in marketings,  1961 Base Year r  100
    1961- 197 1
    State
    Iowa
    Illinois
    Missouri
    Indiana
    Nebraska
    Minnesota
    Ohio
    Wisconsin
    Kansas
    S. Dakota
    Total
    Numb e r
    1961
    (1000 hd)
    18,308
    10,864
    5,771
    7,442
    3,838
    5,726
    4,021
    3,224
    1,766
    2,515
    1962
    
    100.2
    105.6
    99.9
    103.4
    105.8
    99.5
    102.0
    98.9
    112.8
    106.6
    1963
    
    107.8
    112.4
    107.9
    109.6
    111.3
    106.8
    104.3
    104.2
    124. 1
    114.8
    1964
    
    106.5
    113.6
    108.2
    104.4
    114.8
    99,9
    103.9
    103.3
    121. 1
    117.0
    1965
    
    99.6
    99.9
    95. 1
    89.6
    102.8
    83.9
    89.6
    89.5
    112.3
    106. 1
    1966
    -p
    103,2
    95.4
    97.3
    86,8
    105. 1
    85.0
    88.8
    92.0
    111.2
    109.2
    1967
    
    113.6
    108,7
    111.4
    94.5
    118.8
    91.4
    95.0
    97. 3
    132,6
    114,2
    1968
    
    117.2
    104.0
    118.0
    91. 1
    129.4
    92, 1
    95.3
    101,7
    138,7
    122,2
    1969
    
    117. 3
    98- 9
    116. 4
    91, 3
    132,4
    90,7
    95.6
    100.9
    155, 8
    118.9
    1970
    109. 4
    98 -".
    I 18 4
    90. 9
    129. 5
    90. 9
    97.4
    101.4
    154. 1
    118,9
    197 1
    1 2 3 . t.
    106 ^
    131. H
    95 7
    155. 1
    102 5
    102,4
    106. 1
    191= 1
    131. 0
    Total
    N'urnbr i
    1971
    ! 1000 hfir
    1 1 =>< u
    7 b09
    7 124
    5. 952
    5. 870
    4. 1 18
    3,422
    3, 375
    3,296
    

    -------
    Table III-6. Percent of hog producers and percent of hog marketings by size,  ten leading states,  1969
    1-9
    
    
    
    
    
    t— i
    HH
    I— i
    1
    I— <
    Ul
    
    
    
    
    State
    Iowa
    Illinois
    Missouri
    Minnesota
    Indiana
    Nebraska
    Ohio
    Wisconsin
    N. Carolina
    Kentucky
    Average
    farms
    1
    2
    3
    4
    2
    3
    4
    7
    13
    10
    5.
    .2
    .6
    .4
    .8
    .6
    . 1
    .9
    .7
    .8
    .3
    44
    hogs
    .1
    .1
    .1
    .2
    .1
    . 1
    .2
    .3
    .7
    .5
    .24
    10-49
    farms
    10
    17
    23
    24
    18
    21
    26
    30
    43
    39
    25.
    .5
    .5
    .3
    . 1
    .7
    .7
    .3
    . 1
    .8
    .6
    56
    hogs
    1. 3
    2.2
    4. 0
    4.8
    2.5
    4.2
    4.7
    6.6
    10. 1
    10.0
    5.04
    50-99
    farms
    15.
    18.
    22.
    23.
    20.
    22.
    22.
    22.
    18.
    22.
    20.
    9
    8
    5
    4
    1
    7
    5
    0
    2
    0
    81
    hogs
    4.8
    5.7
    9.4
    11.8
    6.5
    10.6
    10. 1
    12. 5
    11.6
    14.6
    9.76
    100-
    farm s
    26
    23
    24
    24
    23
    26
    21
    21
    12
    15
    21.
    .0
    .2
    .3
    .4
    .5
    . 3
    .8
    . 3
    .7
    .9
    94
    199
    200-499
    hogs farms
    15.5
    13.7
    19.5
    23.8
    14.4
    23.9
    18.7
    23.3
    15.0
    20.5
    18.83
    35.2
    Z6.1
    20.7
    18.9
    24.7
    21.6
    18.5
    15.5
    8.0
    9.4
    19.86
    500-
    hogs farms
    44.9
    34.7
    37. 1
    37. 3
    34. 0
    40.2
    34.9
    36.5
    20.4
    26.7
    34.67
    9.4
    9.0
    4.6
    3.7
    8.0
    3.8
    4.7
    2.9
    2. 1
    2. 0
    5. 02
    999
    1, 000 +
    hogs farms
    24.
    25.
    18.
    15.
    24.
    14.
    19.
    14.
    12.
    13.
    18.
    61.8
    8 2.8
    31.2
    7 0.7
    2 2.4
    7 .8
    51.3
    7 .5
    71.4
    8 0.8
    4 1. 37
    hog
    8.
    17.
    11.
    6.
    18.
    6.
    11.
    6.
    29.
    13.
    13.
    Total
    s farms
    8
    8
    6
    4
    3
    3
    9
    1
    5
    9
    06
    100
    100
    100
    100
    100
    100
    100
    100
    100
    100
    100
    hogs
    100
    100
    100
    100
    100
    100
    100
    100
    100
    100
    100
    

    -------
    Employment
    
    Employment in hog production is a function of the number and size of
    production units.  Employment by segment is assumed to be highly cor-
    related with the number of farms with hogs.
    
    Total employment on hog production units approximates 549,000 people.
    Three fourths or about 412,000 of the people  employed on hog production
    units  are located in the Midwest.
                                   111-16
    

    -------
                II.   HOG INDUSTRY FINANCIAL PROFILE
    Financial data depicting "typical hog operations" were limited as there
    is a wide range  of systems and alternative practices in producing hogs.
    Because of this, costs for five model hog operations were used.  These
    models represent different sized operations of which three were open-
    lot systems and the two largest were confinement systems.  Cost data
    used were derived by a private consultant.
                          A.   Plant by Segments
    Financial profiles were developed for five different hog operations,
    varying in size and type of system used. It was assumed that the pro-
    ducers would have farrow-to-finish operations. Operations marketing
    100, 300 and 900 hogs annually were assumed to use open lot manage-
    ment systems.  Once the pigs were weaned,  they would be placed on an
    open dirt lot with concrete flooring only under  the feeders and waterers.
    There would also be a shed for shade and protection from extreme weather.
    For the larger operations involving 2,250 and 7,500 hogs marketed annually
    it was assumed that these would be  totally confined systems in which the
    sows  farrow inside and the hogs are fed-out in confinement.  Producers
    were  assumed  to farrow their sows twice a year and incur cost for all
    inputs used in the operation.
    
    Annual Profits Before Taxes
    Based on the model operations procedures and assumptions, the estimated
    annual pre-tax incomes for the various sized models range from $1,304
    for an operator marketing 100 hogs annually to $18,034 for an operation
    marketing 7,500  hogs annually (Table III-7).  Pre-tax incomes for the open-
    lot operations increased from $1,304 for the small operation to $3,714 for
    the operator marketing 900 head annually.   The differences in the per head
    pre-tax income are explained by the fact that the smaller producer has
    little,  if any, fixed cost for his operation and  also utilizes pasture as a
    source of feed.   The larger open lot operation may tend to have a more
    permanent fixed facility and some  equipment designed specifically for
    the hog operation.  For confinement systems pre-tax income ranged from
    $2, 573 for the 2,250 ma rketing operation to $18, 034 for the ope ration
    marketing 7, 500  head annually.  The difference  in  per head pre-tax
    income is explained by the relatively high per head investment for the
    smaller  confinement system.  This is  attributed to the economies of scale
    that occur as a confinement system increases in size.
    
                                   Ill-17
    

    -------
                    Table III-7.  Estimated pre-tax income and  rate of return on average invested
                               capital and after-tax return on sales for the hog industry
    Financial measure 100 300 900
    Pre-tax net income $1,304 $2,290 $3,714
    Pre-tax ROI* (%) 155-2 56- 9 25< 1
    After-tax ROI* (%) 12K1 44> 4 19lfe
    After-tax return on sales (%) 28.1 14C3 7.8
    2,250 7,500
    $2,573 $18,034
    5.4 15.5
    4, 2 ' 12.1
    2.1 4,5
    h-1            jy /
    ^            —  Average return on fixed investment calculated by financial statement  method.
    00
    

    -------
    After-tax ROI decreases as the size of operation increases for open
    lots systems.  This is due to the extremely low  investment involved with
    the smaller hog operation.  As the size of confinement systems increases,
    the after-tax ROI also  increases.   This is explained by the economies of
    scale that prevail in confinement systems.
    
    Book value of assets,  on which the above  rates of return were calcu-
    lated,  was derived by dividing replacement cost  by two,  plus net working
    capital (current assets minus current  liabilities).  This average  fixed
    investment value is intended to approximate invested capital.
    
    Profitability of the hog industry is dependent on  two  basic factors.  One
    is the  price that  the producer  receives for the finished hog.  Another is
    the price of feed grains.  Increases or decreases in these  prices will
    directly  effect what profits the hog producer will incur.
    
    Annual Cash Flow
    
    Estimated annual cash flow (after tax income  plus  depreciation) and the
    ratio of cash flow to average fixed investment are  shown in Table III-8
    and Table III-9 for the different model operations.  Depreciation was
    computed using industry guidelines for facilities and equipment.
    
    The annual cash  flow varied from $1, 167  for the smallest open lot model
    operation to $32,717 for the largest confinement model operation.  Cash
    flow as a percent of average investment decreased as the size of the
    open lot  operations  increased and increased as the size of  the confinement
    operation increased.  This is explained by the differences  in investment levels
    as explained earlier.
    
    Market (Salvage) Value of Assets
    
    The salvage value of assets used in hog operations are relatively limited.
    Facilities and equipment are designed specifically for hogs with few alter-
    native uses for existing hog facilities.
    
    The open lot hog operation consists of a pen with sheds or  hous'ng for
    shelter.  If the shed is large enough it would be  possible to convert the
    pen and shed to a cattle enterprise. However the feeders and waterers would
    have little value  to alternative enterprises.  It is assumed that for an open
    lot hog operation a salvage value of ten percent of replacement cost is  realistic.
                                      Ill-19
    

    -------
                      T;ibk' lil-H,  Estimated cash flow for the hog industry
    Financial measure                ] 00         300         900         2,250      7,500
    Annual cash flow                $1,167      £2,536     $5,397     $10,407    $32,717
    
    Cash  flow on average
      fixed investment     (%)         138.9        63 0        36.5        21.7        28.2
    

    -------
                            Table III-9.  Estimated cash flow for various sized hog operations
    ts)
    
    
    Annual output (cwt produced)—
    Sales-
    Less variable expenses
    Feed
    Other-
    Less fixed expenses
    Cash earnings
    Less depreciation
    Less interest
    Pre-tax income
    Excluding family labor
    Cash earnings
    Less depreciation
    Les s interest
    Pre-tax income
    
    100
    225.0
    $4, 152
    2, 300
    1,247
    55
    550
    150
    68
    332
    
    1,522
    150
    68
    1, 304
    Number
    300
    675.0
    $12, 454
    8, 115
    3, 756
    165
    418
    750
    294
    -626
    
    3, 334
    750
    294
    2, 290
    of hogs
    900
    2, 025.0
    $37, 361
    24,245
    10,796
    495
    1,825
    2,500
    957
    -1,632
    
    7, 171
    2, 500
    957
    3,714
    
    2, 250
    5, 062.5
    $93,393
    63,450
    18,757
    1, 800
    9,386
    8,400
    3, 045
    -2,059
    
    14, 018
    8,400
    3, 045
    2, 573
    
    7,500
    16,875.0
    $311,344
    210,375
    66,440
    5,970
    28,559
    18,650
    7,315
    2,594
    
    43,999
    18,650
    7, 315
    18, 034
         --  Price uf $18. 45/cwt. was  used.
    
    
    
         --  Assume hogs are sold weighing 225 pounds.
    
    
    
            Includes a charge for family labor.
    

    -------
    F'o r ri t on! mom t'nt s y s t em  to i om e rt to a ltc> ma 11 v e enterprises
    would  require  sorno mod il ications in  the building.   In most cases the
    pens inside the structure would ha\ e  to be removed and possibly a new
    t loci r \\oiilcl be neiessary.  Cattle  is a possible enterprise that could
    >:t:!ize some oi the existing tac'hties    Salvage value is estimated to be
    i'-> percent ol replacement cost tor buildings.
    
    Capital Structure
    
    Investment required to produce market hogs is a function of the number
    ot  hogs an operator desires to produce (Table  III-10).  To produce 100
    market hogs annually requires an  investment ol an  estimated $2,740 or
    SZ7.40  per head marketed.  This would be an  open  lot operation with
    relatively little specialized equipment.  As the marketings of hogs
    produced on an open lot increase.,  so does the  per head investment.
    For an  open lot marketing 900 hogs a year   the per head  investment is
    $43. 80.   This  i s explained in that  as  an ope rat or expands his hog ope r-
    ation.  he purchases more- specialized equipment.
    
    For a confinement hog producing system,  the  cost  per head decreases
    as the  number of marketings increase.  These economies of scale occur
    clue to the more  intensified use of specialized  equipment.
    
    Cost Structu re
    
    Cost for producing hogs  were developed to determine the relative im-
    portance  of various inputs.  Costs were classified  into two categories-
    fixed and variable (Table III-11).
    
    The most significant cost was for feed which accounted for at least 70
    percent of all  cost for all the various sized hog operations.
    
    Cost as a  pe rcent of sales ranged from 68.6 pe rcent for the smallest
    producer to 94. Z pe rcent for the  la rgest produce r (Table 111-12).  This
    wide range can be attributed  to the differences in the type of operation
    analyzed. As the size of the operation became more specialized, the cost
    as a percent of sales tended to stabilize at the 95 percent level.
                                       111-22
    

    -------
    Table 111-10.  Estimated replacement value and working capital  requirements for the hog industry
    Capital Component
    Replacemant value of facilities
    and equipment
    Net working capital
    100
    1, 500
    1, 240
    300
    7, 500
    4, 335
    900
    25, 000
    14,420
    2, 250
    84, 000
    37, 600
    7, 500
    186, 500
    128, 048
        Replacement value of
          total assets                     2,740     11,835       39,420      121,600     314,548
    

    -------
                  Table III-11.  Total investment and annual cost in producing nogs (farrow to finish operation)
    Number ot Hogs Marketed Annually
    
    Investment Costs
    Annual Fixed Cost
    Insurance Zi Taxes
    Interest on Investment
    Depreciation
    Total Fixed Cost
    Annual Variable Cost
    Feed
    Veterinary
    Utilities
    Marketing
    Interest on Breeding Stock
    Labor (hired)
    Labor Family (Includes Mgt.)
    Total Variable Cost
    Total Costs
    Total Cost Excluding Family Labor
    100
    1 . 500
    
    55
    45
    150
    250
    
    2,300
    100
    25
    150
    23
    -
    972
    3,570
    3,820
    2,848
    300
    7, 500
    
    165
    225
    750
    1, 140
    
    8,115
    300
    90
    450
    69
    -
    2,916
    11,940
    13.080
    10, 164
    900
    25,000
    
    495
    750
    2,500
    3,745
    
    24,245
    900
    900
    1,350
    207
    2,300
    5,346
    35,248
    38,993
    33,647
    2,250
    84,000
    
    1,800
    2,520
    8,400
    12,720
    
    63,450
    2,250
    3,800
    3,375
    525
    4,700
    4,632
    82,732
    94,452
    89,820
    7,500
    186,500
    
    5,970
    5,590
    18,650
    30,210
    
    210,375
    11,250
    14,500
    11,250
    1,725
    14,000
    15,440
    278,540
    308,750
    293,310
    Assumptions:
         - Assume a  sow farrows twice a year with an average of 1 5 pigs per year.
         - Small operations (5-8 sows)  have little investment for swine production,  existing facilities are used by
          many of tnese enterprises.
         - Assume 450 pounds of feed will produce 100 pounds of market hogs.  Small operations r-duce fe^d cost
          by using more pasture.   Hogs will be marketed at 225 pounds.
         - Marketing cost includes trucking or transportation and commissions.
    

    -------
    Table III-12.  Estimated costs  for the hog industry
    100
    Item
    Sales
    Raw materials (Feed)
    Direct operating costs-
    Indirect operating costs
    Depreciation
    Interest
    H-t
    E Total before tax cost
    i
    N)
    
    $
    4, 152
    2, 300
    275
    55
    150
    68
    2,848
    
    %
    100.0
    55.4
    6.6
    1.3
    3.6
    1.6
    68.6
    
    300
    $
    12,454
    8, 115
    840
    165
    750
    294
    10, 164
    
    %
    100.
    65.
    6.
    1.
    6.
    2.
    81.
    
    
    0
    2
    7
    3
    0
    4
    6
    
    900
    $
    37,361
    24,245
    5,450
    495
    2, 500
    957
    33,647
    
    %
    100.0
    64.9
    14.6
    1.3
    6.7
    2.6
    90. 1
    
    2,250
    $ '
    93, 393
    63,450
    13, 325
    1,800
    8, 400
    3, 045
    90, 020
    
    %
    100.0
    67.9
    14.3
    1.9
    9.0
    3.3
    96.4
    
    7,500
    $
    311, 344
    210, 375
    51, 000
    5,970
    18,650
    7, 315
    293, 310
    
    %
    100.0
    67.6
    16.4
    1.9
    6.0
    2.3
    94.2
    
    

    -------
                   B.   Ability to Finance New Investments
    Hog producers, in the past,  have relied upon the  Production Credit Assoc-
    iation,  Farmers Home Administratic -, and particularly private financial
    institutions.  Cash flow in a  hog enterprise has always been relatively high.
    This, plus the fact that hogs have tended to be a profitable enterprise have
    caused  private financial  institutions  to be particularly helpful in financing
    new investments in hog facilities.  Because of this,  there  seems to be
    little difficulty in obtaining .additional financing for hog operations.
                                   111-26
    

    -------
                    PART IV:   THE DAIRY INDUSTRY
                     I.   DAIRY INDUSTRY SEGMENTS
                           A.  Types of Firms
    
    Milk production is one of the oldest farm enterprises in agriculture.
    In the early history of U.S. agriculture,  nearly all farmers kept milk
    cows to satisfy their own milk requirements.  With the advent of
    refrigeration, improved transportation and new technology in pro-
    duction,  milk production has been undergoing a revolution.
    
    At present a decreasing percent of all farmers maintain  dairy herds.
    Fewer dairymen with increasingly larger herds now  supply consumers
    with an adequate supply  of milk.   Production is becoming specialized
    with dairying being a full time occupation for an increasing number of
    farmers.
    
    Number and Size of Production Units
    
    In 1969,  the Census  of Agriculture reported 452,852 farms with dairy
    cows,  a decrease of 680,737 units since  1964. W  Declines occurred
    in the number of herds  with 50 or less cows, with significant reductions
    in herds  of  1 - 19 head
                                Number Farms
    Size Herd
    
    1-19
    20-50
    51-99
    100 or more
    1964
    871,987
    215,155
    37,601
    8,846
    ,133,589
    1969
    247,267
    157,309
    38,457
    9,819
    452,852
     Change
    
    -624,720
    - 57,846
         856
         973
    -680,737
    In 1969,  forty-five percent of all cows were in herds  of 20-50 head,
    located on 157,000 farms.  Concentration of cows in this size category
    did not change during the past two census periods.
    _  The 1969 Census included only farms with gross incomes of $2,500 or
       more while the 1964 Census included all farms.  Part of the decrease in
       number of small dairy farms may have resulted from the definition of farms.
                                     IV-1
    

    -------
    Shifts in concentration by herd sizes occurred in those herds under 20
    and greater than 50 head.  Only 15. 2 percent  of all cows were in the
    smaller herds in 1969 compared to 29 percent in 1964 (Table IV-1).
    Cows in herds of 50 or more head increased from 27 percent to 40
    percent during this five year period;
    
                  Percent of Cows
                   in Herds of:             1964          1969
                     1-19                   29           15
                     20-50                  44           45
                     51-99                   3           23
                     100 or more            11           17
    
    Continued increases in herd sizes, and reductions in the number of
    dairymen are anticipated.  New technologies in handling and milking cows
    combined with feed harvesting and storage will require increased invest-
    ments  in a  dairy unit.  These investments will necessitate large produc-
    tion units in order to spread fixed costs over a larger output.  In the near
    future, however, herds of less than 100 cows will prevail with herds of
    50-100 cows  being the dominant herd size.
    
    Volume of  Marketings
    
    Milk production has approximated 120 billion pounds during the past decade
    (Table IV-2).  During the early sixties about 125 billion pounds were pro-
    duced with this amount decreasing by about three percent in the latter part
    of the decade.  Less production was required as total consumption was
    decreasing.
    
    In 1972,  production again equalled 120 billion pounds, the first time since
    1965.  This amount was  needed as total consumption has increased during
    the past three years after declining during most of the 1960's.
    
    Ninety-five percent of all milk produced is presently sold to plants and
    dealers as  whole milk (Table IV-2).  This compares to 84 percent in I960.
    The volume of mi Ik used on farms, so Id as cream and sold directly to
    consumers has been decreasing and represents an insignificant proportion
    of milk marketed.
    
    Over three-fourths  of all milk is presently sold as Grade A milk which is
    elgible for use in fluid products.  In,1950, sixty-one percent of all milk
    sold met Grade A requirements.  Dairy farmers have been increasingly
    converting from the production  of Grade B (manufacturing)  production to
    Grade A •  One of the primary reasons for this conversion is that the price
                                    IV-2
    

    -------
       Table IV-1.  Number of farms with milk cows, by size, and percent
                              of milk cows, 1964 and 1969-
    1964 I/
    
    Size of Herds
    1 - 19
    20 - 50
    51 - 99
    100 or more
    
    No
    Percent
    of
    Farms
    871,
    215,
    37,
    8,
    1,133,
    987
    155
    601
    846
    589
    Farms
    76.
    19-
    3.
    0.
    100.
    9
    0
    3
    8
    0
    Percent
    of
    Cows
    28.
    44.
    16.
    11.
    100.
    6
    0
    3
    1
    0
    No.
    Farms
    247,
    157,
    38,
    9,
    452,
    267
    309
    457
    819
    852
    1969 z/
    Percent
    of
    Farms
    54.6
    34. 7
    8. 5
    2. 2
    100. 0
    
    
    Percent
    of
    Cows
    15.
    44.
    22.
    17.
    100.
    2
    9
    6
    3
    0
    Source:
      !_/ 1964 Agricultural Census, all farms.
    
      —  1969 Agricultural Census.  Farms with Gross Incomes of $2,500
         or more.
                                   IV-3
    

    -------
    Table IV-2.  Total milk production, milk used on farms and marketed,
                             1960-1972, United States
    Milk
    Marketed by
    Farmers
    Sold to Plants
    and dealers
    Year
    I960
    1961
    1962
    1963
    1964
    1965
    1966
    1967
    1968
    1969
    1970
    1971
    1972
    Production
    1
    1
    1
    1
    1
    1
    1
    23.
    25.
    26.
    25.
    27.
    24.
    19-
    118.
    1
    1
    1
    1
    1
    17.
    16.
    17.
    18.
    20.
    1
    7
    3
    2
    0
    2
    9
    7
    2
    1
    0
    5
    3
    Milk used
    on farms
    9-
    8.
    7.
    7.
    6.
    6.
    5.
    5.
    4.
    4.
    4.
    3.
    3.
    2
    4
    7
    1
    5
    0
    5
    2
    7
    3
    0
    7
    5
    as whole
    milk
    103.
    108.
    110.
    111.
    114.
    112.
    109-
    109-
    108.
    108.
    110.
    112.
    114.
    9
    4
    7
    2
    2
    7
    7
    4
    8
    5
    0
    2
    4
    as
    cream
    7.
    6.
    5.
    5.
    4.
    3.
    3.
    2.
    2.
    1.
    1.
    1.
    0.
    9
    9
    9
    1
    4
    7
    0
    4
    0
    6
    2
    0
    8
    Sold Directly
    to Consumers
    2.
    2.
    2.
    1.
    1.
    1.
    1.
    1.
    1.
    1.
    1.
    1.
    1.
    1
    1
    0
    9
    9
    «
    7
    8
    8
    7
    7
    6
    5
    Source:  Dairy Situation, E. R. S. ,  U.S.D. A. , May, 1973.
                                  IV-4
    

    -------
    level of Grade A milk exceeds that of Grade B by a dollar or more per
    hundred weight.  This differential makesthe conversion a profitable
    endeavor.
    
    The value of all milk sold by dairymen last year, was $7, 156 million
    dollars,  an increase of 42 percent relative to 1965.   This increase in
    the gross receipts to farmers has primarily  resulted from increases
    in the price of milk.  The average price received by dairymen for all
    milk in 1972 was $6. 08 per cwt. compared to $4. 81 in  1966.
    
    Age of Production Facilities
    
    There are  no known published studies pertaining to the age of production
    facilities used in farms for milk production.   Data pertaining to age  of
    facilities was obtained from private  sources  and believed to be represen-
    tative information for dairy production units.
    
    Data obtained pertains to the  type of management systems used in handling
    and  milking dairy cows, and the percent of these facilities built  since I960.
    
    Two-thirds of all farms house and milk cows  in  stanchion barns (Table IV-3).
    Most of these facilities are old with  only eight percent  being  built since
    I960.  This type of system prevails  in the Northeast, Lake States and
    portions of the Midwest.
    
    Open lot systems are used by 35 percent of all dairymen.  This sytem
    prevails in the West, Southwest and  South where climatic conditions  do
    not necessitate the housing of cows.  About one-fourth  of these facilities
    have been built since I960.  It is assumed that this system is used by the
    larger dairies in these areas.
    
    Free stall  systems are currently being used to replace stanchion barns in
    the northern milk producing areas and account for about  15 percent of all
    facilities.  About one-half are less than ten years of age.
    
    Overall we can conclude that the average age  of all production systems is
    probably ten years old or older.  The majority of producers  using stanchion
    barns have probably fully depreciated their facilities.  Free  stall systems
    are  relatively new with an estimated average  age of five  years.  Open lot
    systems are estimated to be five  to ten years of age.
                                     IV-5
    

    -------
    Table IV-3. Types of facilities used by dairymen,  1970
                                         Percent          Percent Built
    Management System	Farms	Since  I960
    
    Stanchion Barns                         66                  8
    
    Open lot
       - loose housing            .           21                 23
       - free stall                           15                 28
    
    Free Stall
       - cold  overed                        13                 49
       - warm covered                       2                 34
    Source:  Estimated,  private source.
                                    IV-6
    

    -------
    Location of Major Production Segments
    
    Wisconsin is the  leading dairy state with 15. 6 percent of all cows.
    Minnesota ranks  second followed in order by New York, California,
    Pennsylvania, Iowa, Ohio, Michigan, Texas and Kentucky.   Sixty-
    one percent of all dairy cows are located in these ten states.
    
    All states have some dairy cows as milk production has traditionally
    been located  adjacent to consuming areas.   The number of cows per
    state range from a low of 6, 000 in  Rhode Island to 1, 832, 000 head in
    Wisconsin (Figure IV-1).
    
               Leading Dairy States           Average No.  Cows - 1972
              Wisconsin                              1 , 832
              Minnesota                                932
              New York                                920
              California                                778
              Pennsylvania                              684
              Iowa                                      458
              Ohio                                      436
              Michigan                                 427
              T exa s                                    358
              Kentucky                                 325
    
    Since I960 the average number of milk cows on farms has declined by
    5, 789, 000 head, a decrease of 33.0 percent.  Cow numbers in 1972
    equalled 11, 710,000 head compared to  17,499,000 head in I960.  The
    rate of decline has  decreased during the past three years to about one
    percent decrease annually.
    
    All major dairy  states had significant  decreases in milk cow numbers
    with the exception of Florida and California. Cow numbers increased
    in Florida by 11 percent and dropped by only one percent in California.
    
    Since 1970,  cow numbers have increased in Wisconsin, Florida, Idaho,
    Utah, Washington,  California, Vermont, Texas.  Increases in these
    states have partially offset declines in  other states.
    
                                              Average number
               Year                          of cows - U. S.
                                                 -1,000-
    
               1960                             17>499
               1965                             14,953
               1970                             12j000
    
               1971                             11,842
                                                11,710
                                    IV-7
    

    -------
    I
    00
       Figure IV-1.   Number of milk cows,  1972, and percent change, 1965-1972.
    
    
                     NOTE:  Top figure -- Average number of milk cows,  1972 (thousands).
                              Bottom figure -- Percent change since  1965.
    

    -------
    Level of Technology
    
    The level of technology used in milk production can best be evaluated
    by using production per cow as a standard  for measurement.  Using
    this criterion for measuring the level of technology, the conclusion
    can be drawn that the level of technology  used has been increasing,
    but is not being used at the available  optimum level.
    
    Significant increases  in production per cow have occurred.  Since
    I960, production per  cow increased by 3,242 pounds equalling 10,271
    pounds per cow for the United States.
    
                                              Milk Production
               Year                           Per Cow - U.S.
                                                 -pounds -
    
                I960                              7,029
                1965                              8,305
                1970                              9,747
                1972                             10,271
    
    Increased production has been a function of better breeding, improved
    feeding, and improved management.  An increasing number of cows
    are being "challenged fed".  This involves feeding increased amounts
    of concentrates  to challenge the genetic  ability of a cow to produce  milk.
    Challenge feeding has not been universally adopted by dairymen.  This
    is evident by the variation in productionper cow by states.   Production
    per cow is greatest in the states of California, Arizona, Washington,
    and Colorado.  The lowest production records are in the Mississippi,
    Alabama, Louisiana, andArkansas.  The difference in production per
    cow between California and Mississippi  is 7,023 pounds.
    
    Part of the variation  in production among states may be explained by
    differences  in climatic  conditions which can influence milk production.
    Most of the  variation, however, is a function of the level of technology
    employed.
    
    Generally, the use of capital and level of management  employed in  the
    West,  Southwest, and New York -New England area  has been superior
    relative to the South, South Atlantic, and portions of the Midwest.
                                       IV-9
    

    -------
    Level of Integration
    
    The production and distribution of dairy products involves the successive
    activities of dairy farming, processing or manufacturing, merchandising,
    wholesaling and retailing.  Vertical integration is the process of linking
    together under one ownership of two or more of these activities.  Some
    vertical integration has occurred in the dairy industry involving production
    units, but the volume of milk produced is insignificant.  In some areas
    producers have  integrated forward by establishing small processing and
    distribution outlets.  In other cases processors have integrated backwards
    by establishing their own herds.  In both cases the volume of milk represents
    a very small percent of all milk produced.
    
    Level of Diversification
    One measure of the level of diversification in dairying is to express
    dairy sales as a proportion of total farm sales.  If dairy sales represent
    a low percent of total farm sales we  can conclude that farmers are highly
    diversified.  If the ratio is high, specialization exists.
    
    A U.S.D.A.  report released  in July  1970,  followed the preceding rationale.
    In the Northeastern states 85 percent of farm income was derived from
    the  sales of milk and dairy animals (Table  IV-4).
    
    Specialization was greatest in the Northeast, Delta States, Pacific, and
    Southern Plains.  In the Corn Belt, the Northern Plains and Appalachian
    areas were more diversified with dairying  accounting for less than one-
    half of farm income.
            B.  Number of Plants and Employment by Segments
    
    In 1969, the Census of Agriculture reported 452,652 farms with dairy cows.
    Over half of these farms were small with less than 20 cows per farm.
    
                 Size Herd                    Number Farms
                 1-19                            Z47.267
                 20 - 50                         15/.809
                 51 - 99                          38,457
                 100 +                             9.819
                                                 452,852
                                     IV-10
    

    -------
           Table IV-4. --Distribution of  farms reporting dairy sales by the proportion of total
                                  sales from dairy sources, by region, 1964
    Percentage of
    total farm sales
    from dairy sources
    
    10-29 	
    30-49 	
    50-69 	
    70-89 	
    90-100 	
    Average, all farms..
    Northeast
    
    21
    1
    2
    8
    42
    47
    85
    • Lake
    : States
    
    4
    6
    17
    25
    40
    8
    63
    Corn
    Belt
    
    : Northern :
    : Plains :
    
    25 62
    24 15
    19 13
    15 6
    16 4
    2 21
    •Percentaee of total
    37
    16
    Appala-
    chian
    of farms
    : Delta
    : States
    surveyed
    : Southern :
    : Plains :
    I/ 	
    15 4 14
    28 11 4
    20 10 5
    16 6 11
    12 23 39
    9 46 27
    farm sales from dairy sources-
    42
    73
    68
    Pacific 1
    
    9
    2
    6
    14
    38
    31
    72
    Total
    
    3/
    11
    11
    3/
    If
    2/
    54
    I/  Data may not  add to 100 due to rounding.
    7/  Less than 0.5 percent.
    3/  Data not computed.
    
    Source:  "Farms Reporting Dairy Sales in 1964,"  U. S.D.A., E.R.S. ,  in cooperation with Minnesota
             Agricultural Experiment Station,  University of Minnesota, June, 1970.
    

    -------
    Employment on farm units were estimated assuming that as size
    of herds increased there would be a proportioned increase in labor
    requirements.  It  was assumed that all dairy farms with less than
    50 cows would require one full-time man, farms with 51-99 cows
    would require two men, and farms with  100 or more cows would
    require an an average of six men.
    Size Herd
    
    1-19
    20-50
    51-99
    100 +
     Number-
     Farms
    
    247,Z67
    157,309
     38,457
      9,819
    452,852
    Estimated  Labor
     Required per
          Farm
    
            1
            1
            2
            6
     Total
     labor
    required
    
    247,267
    157,309
     76,914
     50.914
    540,914
    An estimated 541,000 persons are employed on dairy farms.  Eighty-
    four percent of total labor requirements are filled by individual
    entrepreneurs and their families.  The remaining 16 percent or
    88,000 persons, represent hired labor.
              C.  Relationships of Segments to Total Industry
    
    Number of Production Units
    Of the 452,852 dairy farms in 1969, fifty-four percent were located in
    the ten leading milk producing  states (Figure IV-2).  The largest number
    of dairy farms are located in the midwest and northeastern areas of the U. S.
    
    Wisconsin has the largest number of dairy farms with about 58,000 units
    (Figure IV-2). Minnesota ranks second followed in order by Iowa,  New
    York, Pennsylvania,  Missouri, Kentucky, Ohio,  Michigan, Tennessee,
    Texas and Illinois. Dairy units in these areas, with the exception of
    Texas, are  relatively small with most cows in herds of less than fifty
    head  (Table IV-5).
    
    The size of  da^ry  herds varies significantly by state.   In Florida,  California,
    Arizona,  and New Mexico over  70 percent of all cows are in herds  of 100
    or more head. In contrast  only 3 percent of the cows in New York and  one
    percent in Wisconsin are concentrated in these larger  herds.
                                    IV-12
    

    -------
    Figure IV-2.  Number of farms with dairy cows and farms with herds of 100 or more cows,  1969.
    
                  Note:  Top figure:  Total number farms with dairy cows.
                        Bottom figure:  Number of farms with milk cow herd of 100 or more head.
    

    -------
    Table IV-5. Number of farms and percent of dairy cows, by size
                  of herd, by ten leading states, 1969
    Size of Herd
    
    Wisconsin
    No. farms
    % farms
    % cows
    Minne s ota
    No. farms
    % farms
    % cows
    New York
    No. farms
    % farms
    % cows
    California
    No. farms
    % farms
    % cows
    Pennsylvania
    No. farms
    % farms
    % COWS
    Iowa
    No. farms
    % farms
    % cows
    Ohio
    No. farms
    % farms
    % cows
    Michigan
    No. farms
    % farms
    % cows
    1-19
    
    15,197
    26.3
    11. 1
    
    18,325
    45.9
    23.4
    
    3,936
    17.4
    4.7
    
    1,877
    34.8
    1.3
    
    6,954
    31.6
    10.4
    
    18,445
    64.4
    29.8
    
    9,711
    53.0
    20.5
    
    6,051
    41.2
    15.0
    20-49
    
    37,087
    64.1
    67.7
    
    19,986
    50. 1
    65.2
    
    13,085
    57.7
    49.5
    
    695
    12.9
    3.5
    
    12,302
    56.0
    60
    
    9, 136
    31.9
    55. 5
    
    6,989
    38. 1
    52. 1
    
    6,800
    46.3
    51.6
    50-99
    
    5,258
    9.1
    18.6
    
    1,482
    3.7
    10.0
    
    4,858
    21.5
    34.4
    
    723
    13.4
    8.0
    
    2,417
    11.0
    23.3
    
    961
    3.4
    12.4
    
    1,445
    7.9
    21.7
    
    1,558
    10.6
    24. 5
    100 +
    
    322
    0.5
    2.6
    
    98
    0.3
    1.4
    
    742
    3.4
    11.4
    
    2, 104
    38.9
    87.2
    
    297
    1.4
    6.3
    
    82
    0.3
    2.3
    
    184
    1.0
    5.7
    
    263
    1.9
    8.9
    Total
    
    57,864
    100
    100
    
    39,891
    100
    100
    
    22,621
    100
    100
    
    5,399
    100
    100
    
    21,970
    100
    100
    
    28,624
    100
    100
    
    18,329
    100
    100
    
    14,672
    100
    100
                                  IV-14
    

    -------
                         Table IV-5. (continued)
    Size of Herd
    
    Texas
    No. farms
    % farms
    % cows
    Kentucky
    No. farms
    % farms
    % cows
    1-19
    
    10,348
    74.0
    8.2
    
    14,322
    74
    34.9
    20-49
    
    1,265
    9.0
    14.0
    
    4, 147
    21.4
    42.8
    50-99
    
    1,586
    11.4
    33.9
    
    766
    4.0
    17.0
    100 +
    
    781
    5.6
    43.9
    
    109
    0.6
    5.3
    Total
    
    13,980
    100
    100
    
    19,344
    100
    100
    Source:  1969 Agricultural Census, Farms with gross income of $2,500 or more.
                                   IV-15
    

    -------
    Most significant, however, are the absolute number of farms with herds
    of 100 or more cows (Figure IV-2).   Larger herds have existed in California
    and Florida for years, but have more recently emerged in all states.
    
    The number of farms with 100 or more cows and percent of cows
    controlled by the larger  producers for the ten leading dairy states are
    as follows:
    
           State                      Number of Farms     Percent of Cows
           Wisconsin                       322                  2. 6
           Minnesota                        98                  1.4
           New York                       742                 11.4
           California                     2,104                 87.1
           Pennsylvania                     297                  6. 3
           Iowa                              82                  2.3
           Ohio                             184                  5.7
           Michigan                        263                  8. 8
           Texas                           781                 43.9
           Kentucky                        109                  5. 3
    
    Since 1965 there have been slight changes in the concentration of dairy
    cows by regions.  Concentration increased slightly in the West, South-
    west, Eastern Cornbelt and the New York - New England area.  Decreases
    occurred in the  South and Western cornbelt.
    
    Milk Production
    Wisconsin is the leading milk producing state accounting for 16. 3 percent
    of all milk in 1972.  California ranks second followed in order by New
    York and  Minnesota.  The combined marketings from these four states
    account for  42 percent of all milk (Table IV-6).
    
    Milk production is concentrated in the midwest, northeast and Pacific
    coast.   Of the fifteen leading states,  seven are located in the  midwest,
    three in the northeast, two in the Pacific coast, two in the midsouth
    and one in the south central area (Table IV-6).
    
    Production per cow is highest in the western states with the northeast
    ranking second.  California leads the nation  with production  per cow of
    13,406 pounds.  Arizona  ranks second and Washington third.
    
    The  lowest production occurs in the south and south central states.
    Mississippi averages only 6,383 pounds per cow, the lowest average in
    the nation.  The top five and low five states in production per cow, for
    1972, are as follows:
    
                                     IV-16
    

    -------
    Table IV-6.  Pounds of milk produced, rank of states by number cows,
        and production per cow, fifteen leading milk producing states,  1972
    
    State
    
    Wisconsin
    California
    New York
    Minnesota
    Pennsylvania
    Michigan
    Ohio
    Iowa
    Texas
    Missouri
    Illinois
    Kentucky
    Washington
    Tennessee
    Vermont
    Milk
    Production
    -million pounds -
    19,079
    10,327
    9,985
    9,295
    6,880
    4,802
    4,405
    4,330
    3,300
    2,918
    2,741
    2,357
    2,250
    2,048
    1,993
    Number of
    Dairy Cows
    Rank -by States
    
    1
    4
    3
    2
    5
    8
    7
    6
    9
    11
    12
    10
    17
    13
    16
    Milk Production
    Per Cow
    
    10,719
    13,406
    11,076
    10,279
    10,279
    11,513
    10,408
    9,838
    9,444
    9,365
    9,890
    7,785
    12,538
    8,475
    10,400
                                     IV-17
    

    -------
           Top Five States                  Prod/Cow/lbs.
    
           California                           13,406
           Arizona                             12,800
           Washington                         1Z.538
           Colorado                            11,633
           Michigan                            11,513
    
           Low Five States
    
           North Dakota                         7,554
           Arkansas                            7,313
           Louisiana                            7,303
           Alabama                             7,183
           Mississippi                          6,383
    
           United States                        10, 271
    
    Employment
    
    Employment on milk production units is highly correlated with the number
    of production units.  This is particularly true for the corn belt, northeast,
    and mid-south where  dairying is primarily a farm family enterprise.  In
    California, Arizona and Florida outside labor is required to maintain the
    larger herds which prevail  in those states.
                                     IV-18
    

    -------
              II.   DAIRY INDUSTRY FINANCIAL PROFILE
    Financial profiles were developed for six different sizes of production
    units and three methods of holding dairy cows.  This methodology was
    used to more fully represent management systems used for various
    size herds.
                         A.   Plants by Segments
    
    Financial profiles were developed for milk production units with herds
    of 25, 50, 100, 200, 500 and 1, 000 cows.  Cows in herds of 25 and 50
    head were assumed to be housed in stanchion barns.  This system is
    prevalent in the major milk producing areas of the North Central, Lake
    States and New York-New England areas.  Herds of 100 and 200  cows
    were assumed to  be housed in loose housing,  a management practice
    which is increasing in the North as herd sizes increase.  Herds  of 500
    to 1, 000 head were assumed to be in open lots,  a management practice
    conducive for large herds, and widely practiced in the  South, Southwest
    and West.
    
    All model plants were assumed  to be operating at 100 percent capacity.
    Level of technology used varied by segments, increasing as herd sizes
    increased.
    
    Annual  Profits  Before Taxes
    Milk producers that are included in our study showed after-tax return
    on sales from 3 to 7 percent (Table IV-7).  After-tax ROI is estimated at
    between 4.6 percent to 9.0 percent.  The low level of these returns may
    be attributed to high levels of investment required as compared to sales.
    
    There is significant differences in profitability due largely to different
    types of operations and the amount of labor that the  farmer operator is
    able to contribute to the overall operation.
    
    Annual Cash Flows
    
    Estimated annual cash flows (after-tax income plus  depreciation) and cash
    flow on average fixed investment are shown in Tables IV-8 and IV-9 for
    selected model operations.   Depreciation schedules for operations indi-
    cated are $23/cow per year, 5 percent per year  of original building invest-
    ment and 7.5 percent per year of original equipment investment.
    
                                   IV-19
    

    -------
    Table IV-7.  Estimated pre-tax income and rate of return on average invested capital and
                       after-tax return on sales for dairy farms by size of herd,  1971
    Size of Herd
    Financial Measure 25 50 100 200 . 500
    Pre-tax net income ($) 1,851 1,523 5,523 7,253 21,834
    Pre-tax ROI* (%) H-5 5- 9 10.9 7.5 11.0
    After-tax ROI* (%) 9-0 4.6 8.5 5.9 8.6
    After-tax return on sales (%) 7.4 3.0 5.5 3.6 4.4
    " / Average return on fixed investment calculated by financial statement method.
    ro
    0
    1,000
    46,010
    12. 2
    8. 1
    3.9
    
    
    

    -------
                    Table IV-8.  Estimated cash flow for dairy farmers, by size of herd,  1971
                                                                      Size of Herd
    Financial Measure
     25
     50
    100
    200
      500
    1,000
    Annual cash flow ($)
    3,196      3,868
                9,788
                15,928       36,661
                              67,016
    Cash flow on average fixed
      investment (%)
     19-9
    14.9
    19-3
    16. 5
    18. 5
    17.7
    

    -------
                     Table IV-9.   Estimated cash flow for dairy herds by number of cows,  1971.
    IN)
    
    ts)
    
    Utilization
    Annual Output (100 Ibs. )
    Sales
    Milk ($6.20)
    Calves
    Total
    Fixed Expenses
    A I
    Variable Expenses —
    Cash Earnings
    Depreciation
    Interest
    Pre-Tax Income
    Excluding Family Labor
    Cash Earnings
    Less Depreciation
    Less Interest
    Pre-Tax Income
    25i/
    100%
    3,000
    18,600
    1,020
    19,620
    292
    21,075
    -1,747
    1,752
    900
    -4,399
    4,503
    1,752
    900
    1,851
    so y
    100%
    6, 000
    37,200
    1,980
    39, 180
    387
    39,400
    -607
    2, 680
    1,440
    -4,727
    5,643
    2,680
    1,440
    1,523
    Size of Herd
    100-/ 200 -^
    100%
    12, 000
    74,400
    3,900
    78, 300
    767
    69,900
    7,633
    5,480
    2,880
    -727
    13,883
    5,480
    2,880
    5,523
    100%
    24,000
    148, 800
    7,800
    156,600
    1,367
    138,500
    16, 733
    10,270
    5,460
    1, 003
    22,983
    10,270
    5,460
    7,253
    500 U
    100%
    60, 000
    372, 000
    19,500
    391,500
    2,066
    343, 000
    46,434
    19,630
    11,220
    15,584
    52, 684
    19,630
    11,220
    21,834
    1,000 I/
    100%
    120, 000
    744, 000
    39,000
    783,000
    3,350
    682, 000
    97,650
    36,590
    21, 300
    39,760
    103,900
    36,590
    21,300
    46,010
         L' Cows are housed in stanchion barns.
    
         _' Cows are housed in loose housing.
    
    
         _ Open lots.
         A I
    
         — Includes $6,250 family labor charge.
    

    -------
    Cash flows are composed of approximately 50% depreciation and 50%
    earnings.  This yields some stability to cash flows; however, cash
    flows are still heavily dependent upon milk and feed prices.
    
    Producers who generate cash flows of less than $10, 000 annually are
    assumed to consume the cash flow in retiring government insured and
    other loans and to provide funds to live on.  These producers typically
    do not attempt to reinvest  depreciation and earnings nor accumulate
    them to replace worn out facilities.
    
    Producers who'generate more than $10, 000 annual cash flows are
    assumed to consume the cash flow to retire government insured and
    other loans and to provide funds to live on.  The  residual after  providing
    the above items is assumed to be reinvested or distributed to partners or
    other investors.
    
    Market (Salvage) Value of  Assets
    
    The salvage value of dairy operations  is  dependent on the type of manage-
    ment  systems used.  Stanchion operations generally have older facilities.
    Stanchion barns with some  modofications  could be used for housing other
    enterprises.   However,  the age of the facility limits the amount of re-
    modelong that would be possible.  For stanchion dairy operations  the
    estimated salvage value of assets, at most, would be  ten percent of
    replacement  value.
    
    Loose housing dairy operations consist of a large open building with an
    adjacent milking parlor.  These operations  are relatively new and could
    be modified to house other enterprises without much difficulty.   Estimated
    salvage value of assets for a loose house  dairy operation is assumed to be
    40 percent of the replacement  value.
    
    Open  lot dairy operations consist of open  fenced lots with shelters and
    central milking parlor.  Alternate uses of the milking parlor are rel -
    lively  non-existent.   In some cases the fences and shelters could be used
    for alternative large animal enterprises.  To do this, however, would
    not change the general function of the lot.  Estimated salvage value for
    this type of operation is assumed to be 10 percent of replacement value.
                                   IV- 23
    

    -------
    Capital Structures
    
    Investment required to operate dairies is in direct relationship with
    the number of cows being milked (Table IV-10).  To milk 25 cows re-
    quires an estimated investment of $30,000,  100 cows require $96,000,
    and a 1, 000 cow operation would require an investment of $710, 000.
    It should be noted that as size of the cow herd increases, the types of
    milking systems  used changes.
    
    Cost Structure
    
    Model plant data  were developed to  estimate the cost structure of six
    representative operations.  Costs associated with milk production were
    classified into two categories -- fixed and variable (Table IV-H).
    
    Fixed expenses were defined as those which do not vary as  output
    changes.  These  expenses include:
    
              depreciation
              insurance
              taxes
              interest on building and equipment.
    
    Variable costs were  defined as those  costs which do vary with output.
    Costs included were:
    
              feed
              milk hauling
              insurance  and taxes on cattle
              bedding
              breeding costs
            -  health  care
              interest on cattle
              other miscellaneous costs.
    
    Variable costs comprise about 90 percent of the  annual costs for all size
    operations.  A major component of variable costs is feed which accounts
    for over 70 percent of these costs.
    
    Feed costs comprise about 56  percent of total sales for all size oper-
    ations (Table IV-12).  Direct operating expenses for all but the  smallest
    operator vary between 25. 1 and 28. 4 percent of sales.  Depreciation and
    interest expense  both decrease as a percent of sales as herd sizes increase.
    
    
                                    IV-24
    

    -------
                    Table IV-10. Estimated replacement value and working capital requirements for dairy
                                              farms, by size of herd,  1971
                                         	Size of Herd	
    Capital Component	25       50        100         200         500           1,000
    
    
    Replacement value of facilities,
     dairy herd, and equipment ($)       30,000   48,000     96,000    182,000      374,000     710,000
    
    Net working capital ($)                1,045    1,815      2,740      5,355       11,500      22,600
    
    
    Replacement value of total
     assets ($)                          31,045   49,815     98,740    187,355      385,500     732.000
    <;
    i
    CsJ
    

    -------
                              Table IV- 11.  Estimated costs for dairy farms, by size of herd, 1971
                                                                 Size of Herd
                                 25
                       50
                        100
                                                                                  200
                                                                       500
                                                                        1000
    Item
     $
    $
                                                           $
    $
    $
    $
    Sales
    
    
    Raw materials
    
                         *i*
    Direct operating costs''
    
    
    Indirect operating costs
    
    
    Depreciation
    
    
    Interest
    
    
    Total before-tax cost
    19,620  100.0  39,180  100.0  78,300  100.0  156,600   100.0 391,500  100.0
    
    
    11,000   56.1  22,000   56.2  44,000   56.2   88,000    56.2 235,500   60.1
    
    
     3,825   19.5  11,150   28.4  19,650   25.1   44,250    28.3 101,250   25.9
       292    1.5     387    1.0     767    1.0    1,367
    
    
     1,752    8.9   2,680    6.8   5,480    7.0   10,270
    
    
       900    4.6   1,440    3.7   2,880    3.6    5,460
                                               .8    2,066    .5
    
    
                                              6.5   19,630   5.0
    
    
                                              3.5   11,270   2.9
    17,769   90.6  37,657   96.1  72,777   92.9  149,347    95.3  369,716  94.4
                                     783,000  100.0
    
    
                                     471,000  60.1
    
    
                                     204,750  26.2
    
    
                                       3,350     .4
    
    
                                      36,590   4.7
    
    
                                      21,300   2.7
    
    
                                     736,990  94.1
    —  Excluding family labor
       [SJ
       cr-
    

    -------
    Table IV- 12. Total investment and annual costs for dairy herds by number of cows,  1971
    Size of Herd
    
    Investment
    Buildings
    Equipment
    Cattle
    Total investment
    Annual Fixed Cost
    Depreciation
    Buildings
    Equipment
    Cows
    Insurance
    Taxes
    Interest (Bldg. k Equip)
    Total fixed cost
    Annual Variable Cost
    Feed
    Bedding
    Breeding
    Veterinary
    Supplies
    Power -fuel
    Auto & tractor
    Insurance & tax
    Milk hauling
    Miscellaneous
    25i'
    
    9, 000
    8, 500
    12, 500
    30, 000
    
    540
    637
    575
    117
    175
    525
    4, 038
    
    11, 000
    1, 000
    250
    450
    250
    200
    175
    50
    1,200
    250
    50^'
    
    13, 000
    10, 000
    25, 000
    48, 000
    
    780
    750
    1, 150
    157
    230
    690
    3, 757
    
    22, 000
    2, 000
    500
    900
    500
    400
    350
    100
    2, 400
    500
    100^
    
    18, 000
    28, 000
    50, 000
    96, 000
    
    1, 080
    2, 100
    2, 300
    307
    460
    1, 380
    7, 627
    
    44, 000
    4, 000
    1, 000
    1, 800
    1, 000
    800
    800
    200
    4, 800
    1, 000
    20<£'
    
    32,000
    50, 000
    100,000
    182, 000
    
    1,920
    3,750
    4,600
    547
    820
    2,460
    14, 097
    
    88, 000
    8, 000
    2, 000
    3, 600
    2, 000
    1, 600
    1, 000
    400
    9, 600
    2, 000
    500^
    
    78, 000
    46, 000
    250, 000
    374, 000
    
    4, 680
    3, 450
    11, 500
    826
    1, 240
    3,720
    25, 416
    
    235,500
    5, 000
    9, 000
    5, 000
    4, 000
    4, 000
    1, 000
    24,500
    5, 000
    1,000^
    
    144, 000
    66, 000
    500, 000
    710, 000
    
    8,640
    4, 950
    23, 000
    1, 340
    2, 010
    6, 300
    46,240
    
    471, 000
    10, 000
    18, 000
    10, 000
    8, 000
    8, 000
    2, 000
    45, 000
    10, 000
                                                                  continued	
    

    -------
         Table IV-12.  Total investment and annual costs for dairy herds by number of cows,  1971  (continued)
    Size of Herd
    25^
    Annual Variable Cost (con't)
    Interest (Cattle)
    Labor!/
    Total variable cost
    Total Cost
    Total Cost (excludes family labor)
    
    6,
    21.
    25,
    19,
    
    375
    250
    450
    488
    238
    50^
    
    750
    9,750
    40, 150
    43, 907
    37, 657
    100^
    
    1,
    10,
    71,
    79,
    72,
    
    500
    500
    400
    027
    777
    200^
    
    3,
    19,
    141,
    155,
    149,
    
    000
    750
    550
    647
    397
    500^
    
    7,
    50,
    350,
    '375,
    369,
    
    500
    000
    000
    916
    666
    1, 000^
    
    15,
    100,
    697,
    743,
    736,
    
    000
    000
    000
    240
    990
    —  Cows are housed in stanchion barns.
    
    
    
    —  Cows are housed in loose housing.
    
    
    
    —  Open lots.
    
    
    4/
    —  Includes $6,250 family labor charge.
    IV
    
    00
    

    -------
                  B.   Ability to Finance New Investments
    
    Milk production is one of the more profitable farm enterprises with a
    good cash flow.  The latter is generally large enough to pay off invest-
    ments within a five year period.
    
    Another advantage of dairying, from a financial institution's viewpoint,
    is that dairymen receive a monthly or bi-monthly payments for milk
    sales.  This enables payment of debts on a continuous basis rather than
    when  animals are sold or  crops are harvested.
    
    Dairymen are good credit risks and should have little  difficulty in ob-
    taining investment capital.
                                    IV-29
    

    -------
                     PART V:   THE SHEEP INDUSTRY
                     I.   SHEEP INDUSTRY SEGMENTS
                           A.  Types of Firms
    Sheep production is  scattered throughout the United States with all
    states  reporting some production.  Most production,  however, is
    concentrated in the western portion of the nation.
    
    Sheep thrive under a wide range and  variety of physical and biological
    conditions.  They graze well on terrain too rough, high and arid to
    be habitable by other domesticated animals.  They utilize plants
    unacceptable to other animals.  Also, sheep blend well in a size
    range either as a  supplementary farm enterprise or a highly spe-
    cialized enterprise.
    
    With these attributes, sheep production might be expected to have had
    significant increases in production.  However, the opposite has occurred
    with the number of sheep declining during the past several decades.
    This decline has  resulted because of a number of factors  including
    declining per capita  consumption of lamb and wool, and low wool prices.
    A once thriving industry has been and is,  declining and now plays a
    secondary role in the livestock and poultry economy of the United States.
    
    Number and Size of  Production Units
    
    In 1969> the Census  of Agriculture reported 123,858 farms with  sheep
    and lambs (Table V-l).  This represented a decrease in the number of
    farms  of over 118,000  since 1964.  The decline  in number of farms
    occurred for all size segments, with the greatest decrease occurring for
    those farms with less than 300 head.
    
                                         Number of Farmsi.'
    Farms with
    < 300 Head
    300 - 999
    1,000 -2,499
    2,500 -4,999
    5,000 +
    
    1964
    221,641
    8,687
    3,052
    939
    470
    234,789
    1969
    105,566
    7,406
    2,458
    806
    426
    116,672
    —  Includes only those farms with breeding herds.
    
                                       V-l
    

    -------
         Table V-l.  Number of farms selling sheep and lamb, percent
            of farms and sheep and lambs sold, by size of enterprise,
                                    1969
    Number of Sheep
    and Lambs on Farm
    
    
    
    
    1
    2
    
    1 -
    25 -
    100 -
    300 -
    ,000 -
    ,500 -
    5,000
    24
    99
    299
    999
    2,499
    4,999
    or more
    Total
    Other
    Total
    Farms
    Number
    44
    44
    17
    7
    2
    
    
    116
    7
    123
    ,190
    , 148
    ,238
    ,406
    ,458
    806
    426
    ,672
    ,186
    ,858
    1969
    Percent
    35.
    35.
    13.
    6.
    2.
    0.
    0.
    94.
    5.
    100.
    7
    6
    9
    0
    0
    7
    3
    2
    8
    0
    Percent of Sheep
    and Lambs Sold
    
    1
    1
    1
    1
    1
    1
    3.
    0.
    2.
    7.
    7.
    3.
    9.
    94.
    
    5.
    100.
    5
    9
    6
    4
    6
    5
    4
    8
    2
    0
    Source:  1969 Census of Agriculture
                                    V-2
    

    -------
    Production has become slightly more concentrated, with 53 percent
    of all sheep and lambs, in 1969, sold by farmers with 1, 000 or more
    head.  This compares with 47 percent in  1964.  The  slight shifts  in
    concentration to larger units occurred even though there was an exodus
    of larger producers during the interval between census  periods.
    
                                  Percent of Sheep and  Lambs Sold
      Farms with                     1964                1969
    
          <300            .           34.6                28.5
      300 -   999                    17.6                18.4
    1,000 - 2,499                    17.9                18. 6
    2,500 - 4,999                    12. 1                 14. 2
         5,000+                      17.8                20. 3
                                    100.0               100.0
    
    Volume of Marketings
    
    The  number of head, and volume of sheep and lambs sold has been
    steadily decreasing.(Table V-2).  In 1950, slightly over 1.4 billion
    pounds of lamb and mutton were sold by farmers.  Ten years  later
    the voJume had slightly increased to about 1. 6 billion pounds.   By
    the early seventies, the volume sold had decreased to 1.0 billion
    pounds.  This amount represented the lowest level of production
    during the past forty years.
    
    Farm cash receipts from the sale  of mutton and lamb equalled
    $313,502, 000 in 1971, six-tenths of one percent of total farm  in-
    come. In addition farmers received $31, 165,000 from the  sale of
    wool.  Combined receipts from the sale of lamb,  mutton and wool
    equalled $344,667,000.
    
    Sales of lambs and sheep as a  percent of total farm income are
    significant in only a few -western states.  In the leading producing
    states of Texas, Colorado, and California, lamb and sheep sales
    represent less than two percent of total farm sales.
    
                                  Sales of Lamb and Sheep
                                  Thousands of    Percent  of Total
    State                           Dollars       Farm Income
    
    Texas                         $43,424              1.4
    Colorado                        43, 294              3. 2
    California                       24,886              0.5
    Idaho                           20,438              2.8
    Iowa                           18,816              0.4
    Wyoming                        16,879              6.4
    Utah                           13,011              5.8
    Minnesota                       11,579              0.5
    Montana                        11,155              1.7
                                            V-3
    

    -------
       Table  V-2. Number of sheep and lambs marketed and pounds
                      produced, U.S.  1950 to 1971
    Year
    
    1971
    1970
    1965
    I960
    1955
    1950
    
    Sheep
    
    2,206
    2,048
    2,454
    3,572
    2,896
    2,640
    Marketings
    Lambs
    1, 000 head
    12,240
    12,478
    15,213
    19,068
    18,736
    16,486
    Quantity Produced
    Liveweight
    1, 000 Ibs
    1,038,685
    1,092,575
    1,217, 139
    1,628,014
    1,618,013
    1,335,720
    Source: Agricultural Statistics,  U.S.D.A.  1972
                                    V-4
    

    -------
    Age of Production Facilities
    
    Sheep production is one of the oldest forms of agriculture in the United
    States and characterized by limited investment  in capital equipment.
    This is  particularly true for breeding  stock which is maintained pri-
    marily on open range in the west and pastures in the eastern portions
    of the United States.   Production facilities consist of fencing and
    perhaps  some type of winter shelter in colder areas.
    
    In feeding lambs for  market, the average feeder has not made the
    investment in production facilities that has occurred in feeding of hogs
    and cattle.  This was the comment received from various industry
    personnel.  The investments made b /  the average feeder consist of
    sheds for shelter,  self feeders, and automatic waterers.  Feeding is
    done with limited mechanized  equipment.  With limited fixed investment
    the primary costs to feeders is the cost of lambs and feed  supplements.
    Basically, feeding  of lambs involves unsophisticated production systems
    relative  to other livestock and poultry enterprises.
    
    Since production has involved  limited investment in production facilities,
    and since production has declined,  it is unlikely that many new production
    facilities have been constructed in  recent years.  There are exceptions,
    but these new enterprises are a minority.   Therefore, we  conclude
    that facilities are old and in many cases fully depreciated.
    
    Location of Major Producing Segments
    
    The major concentration of ewes are found in the western half of the
    United States with 80  percent of the breeding  stock located in this area.
    Of the ten leading states, measured by the number of ewes,  eight are
    located  in the west (Table V-3). Texas, the leading state,  reported
    2, 530 thousand ewes on farms representing 20 percent of all breeding
    stock.   Wyoming ranked second followed in order by California,  South
    Dakota,  Utah and Montana.
    
    Feeding  of lambs is more widely dispersed than breeding stock.  Colorado
    is the leading state,  based on  number  of lambs  on feed,  with 16. 2 of
    lambs.   Texas ranks  second,  and is followed in  order by Iowa, Nebraska,
    South Dakota, Wyoming, Minnesota, Ohio,  Idaho, and California
    (Table V-3).   These  ten states account for 68 percent of all lambs  fed.
                                        V-5
    

    -------
       Table V-3.  Ranking of states by number of ewes and lambs
                               on feed, 1971
    State
    Number of
    Ewes on Feed
    State
                                                                Number of
                                                              Lambs on Feed
    Texas
    Wyoming
    California
    South Dakota
    Utah
    Montana
    Colorado
    Idaho
    New Mexico
    Ohio
    Iowa
    1
    2
    3
    4
    5
    6
    7
    8
    9
    10
    10
    Colorado
    Texas
    Iowa
    Nebraska
    South Dakota
    Wyoming
    Minnes ota
    Ohio
    Idaho
    California
    
    1
    2
    3
    4
    5
    6
    7
    8
    9
    10
    
    Source:  Agricultural Statistic s ,  U. S.D.A., 1972.
                                      V-6
    

    -------
    Level of Technology and Efficiency
    
    The  level of technology used and efficiencies attained in sheep production
    are considered to be  inferior relative to the production of other livestock
    and poultry. Breeding stock is held on open range and pasture and used
    primarily as scavengers  of grasses  not adaptable for other livestock.
    Breeding stock receive little supplementa 1 feeding resulting in  poor
    fertility and less than desirable  lambing rates.
    
    Lamb feedlots can be  characterized  as having limited investments in labor
    saving technologies.   The typical feedlot, as described by industry
    personnel,  consists of sheds for shelter, self feeders and waterers.
    Roughage and feed is fed  by hand with limited use of available technology
    in roughage handling,  bunk line feeding,  manure disposal, and feeding
    rations.
    
    Level of Integration
    
    Integration  in sheep production and/or feeding is assumed to be limited
    in scope. Breeding herds are controlled by over 100,000 producers,
    with each having a relatively insignificant portion of total breeding stock.
    Producers are integrated to the  extent that some farmers with breeding
    stock do feed out lambs.  This is particularly true in grain producing
    areas.
    
    There is some vertical integration in the feeding of lambs.  The Packers
    and Stockyards Resume of December 15, 1972,  reported that 9- 7 percent
    of all lambs slaughtered, in 1971 , were  fed by or for meat packers.
    This compares to over 13 percent in the two preceding years.  All other
    lambs were assumed to be  fed by independent producers  and  sold on a
    free market.
    
    Level of Diversification
    Sheep production is generally considered to be part of larger diversified
    farm or ranch enterprises.   Range flocks in the West are used to complement
    a total ranch enterprise.  Farm flocks in other areas of the United States
    are  small and considered as  secondary farm enterprises.
    
    Lamb feedlots are usually part of larger  farm production systems involving
    roughage and feed  grain production and/or other cattle feeding.   Lambs
    are  fed to utilize roughage and feed grains.
                                     V-7
    

    -------
            B-  Number of Plants and Employment by Segments
    
    In 1969, the Agricultural Census reported 109,188 farms with sheep
    or lambs.  These producers were further classified by the number
    of sheep and lambs on place.
    
                Inventory of                     Number
               Sheep and Lambs                   Farms
    
                    1-24      ,                 44,190
                   25  - 99                       44,148
                  100  - 299                      17,238
                  300  - 999                       7,406
                1,000  - 23499                     2,458
                2,500  - 4,999                       806
                    5,000 +                         426
                    Other!/                       7,186
                                               123,858
    
    There are no known published data on the number of people employed in
    sheep production.  Due to lack of information we can only assume that
    employment would at least equal the number of farms with sheep and
    lambs and not exceed 150,000 persons.
                 C-  Relationships of Segments to Industry
    
    Of the  123,858 sheep production units  reported in 1969, over 60 percent
    are located in the eastern half of the U.S.   Iowa has the largest number
    of farms with sheep reporting  16,375 units  in 1969 (Figure V-l). Texas
    ranks second followed in order by Ohio, Illinois,  Minnesota, and South
    Dakota.
    
    The size of flocks varies greatly by geographic  area.  Farm flocks are
    common in the eastern half of the U. S. and comprise over 90 percent of
    all production units, but produce less  than a third of all lambs.  Sheep
    ranches  in the V/est vary from 1,500  to 1 0, 000 head per ranch and pro-
    duce more than half the lambs.£'
    
    Variation in size of production units is evident when comparisons are
    made between the ten leading states (Table  V-4).  In Colorado, Wyoming,
    California, Idaho, and Oregon over one-third of all sheep and lambs sold
    are from ranches with 5,000 or more. In Iowa  less than six percent of
    all sales originate  from farms of this  size.
    !_/ Farms which only feed lambs.  Have no breeding herds.
    _' Costs  and Returns,  Migratory-Sheep Ranches,  Utah-Nevada,  1972,  by
       W.D.  Goodsell and M.  Belfield, ERS,  USDA, June,  1973.
                                      V-8
    

    -------
    Figure V-l.  Number of farms with sheep and lambs, 1969
    Source: 1969 U.S. Census of Agriculture
    

    -------
    Table V-4.  Number of farms with sheep and lambs,  percent of farms and sheep and lambs
               sold, by inventories per farm, ten leading states,  1969
    Inventories of
    
    Texas
    N o . Fa r m s
    Percent Farms
    Percent Sold
    Colorado
    No. Farms
    Percent Farms
    Percent Sold
    Wyoming
    No. Farms
    ^ Percent Farms
    i Percent Sold
    o
    California
    No. Farms
    Percent J^arms
    Percent Sold
    South Dakota
    No. Farms
    Percent Fa rms
    Percent Sold
    Idaho
    No. Farms
    Percent Farms
    Percent Sold
    1-
    24
    
    1,549
    15. :,
    .9
    
    423
    19- 9
    1. 0
    
    176
    8.4
    1. 1
    
    
    611
    26.6
    . 7
    
    1,388
    20. 0
    2.2
    
    388
    23.4
    . 7
    25-
    99
    
    2,297
    22. 9
    3. 5
    
    502
    23.6
    1. 8
    
    416
    19. 8
    1. 8
    
    
    565
    24. 6
    1. 8
    
    3,004
    43. 3
    13. 5
    
    485
    29-3
    4. 2
    100-
    299
    
    2,951
    29- 5
    11.6
    
    473
    22. 3
    5. 8
    
    577
    27. 5
    6.8
    
    
    411
    17.9
    4.4
    
    1,655
    23.9
    21.5
    
    402
    24. 3
    7. 3
    300-
    999
    
    2,228
    22. 2
    24. 6
    
    364
    17. 2
    12. 3
    
    478
    22. 8
    14. 9
    
    
    365
    15.9
    14. 2
    
    722
    10. 4
    28. 3
    
    178
    10. 7
    13.4
    1,000-
    2,499
    
    716
    7. 1
    23.7
    
    255
    12. 0
    26. 6
    
    258
    12.3
    22.6
    
    
    177
    7. 7
    16.6
    
    129
    1.9
    14. 1
    
    107
    6. 5
    19. 1
    Sheep and Lambs
    2,500-
    4,999
    
    210
    2. 1
    20. 9
    
    74
    3. 5
    17.9
    
    105
    5.0
    18. 2
    
    
    91
    4.0
    18.1
    
    29
    .4
    10. 9
    
    60
    3.6
    23. 0
    5,000+
    
    66
    . 7
    14. 8
    
    32
    1. 5
    34.6
    
    87
    4.2
    34.6
    
    
    77
    3. 3
    44. 2
    
    6
    . 1
    9. 5
    
    36
    2. 2
    32. 3
    Total
    
    10,017
    100%
    100%
    
    2,123
    100%
    100%
    
    2,097
    100%
    100%
    
    
    2,297
    100%
    100%
    
    6,933
    100%
    100%
    
    1,656
    100%
    100%
    

    -------
                                                Table \' -4 (i-nnt inutd)
    
    
    
    Iowa
    No. Farms
    Pei cent Farms
    Percent Sold
    Montana
    N o . Fa r m b
    Pe rcent. Fa r AI 5
    Percent hold
    Utah
    No. Farru^
    Percent Fa i u, ;
    Per^ eut Soi 1
    Oregon
    No. larr^s
    Percent Farms
    Percent Sold
    in-'entorit s 01 Sh<
    1- 25- 100» 300- 1.UUO-
    21 99 299 999 2,499
    
    7,472 0,151 1.111 2.1., 53
    49. 7 40. 9 7.4 16 .2
    12. S 31- 8 18. 5 2u. o 1C [;
    
    159 t-.H m 5L' 217
    j i -. 24, -i .l.i. 20. ^ o o
    L . 3 57 1 1 r, "'6 T, . v 1
    
    }(>G ,11 i 1 ' - ~ . 1 C 0
    i 7 - _ i . 2 Mi ji ''-j
    r .- i / •'. J . '' '3 4
    
    MJ, "-i2 c.2 i 2.: • ""<
    21. 4 3'). 8 J'o. 5 M. i lo
    20 7. 8 ID. 3 14 '/ R. 4
    'ep and Laa'ibs
    2, "t.OO-
    4,999 5,000+
    
    5 2
    .1 .1
    2.5 3. 1
    
    5n 13
    .: . 2 . b
    i 5 r, 7.7
    
    7 o 25
    J ^ 1.4
    ;• i ! ^ i . 3
    
    1 J 11
    . '•, ,5
    •J.3 47.3
    
    
    Total
    
    15,021
    100%
    100%
    
    2,513
    100%
    100%
    
    1,748
    100%
    100%
    
    2, 367
    100%
    100%
    Source:  19&9 Census of Agriculture
    

    -------
    Lamb and Sheep Production
    
    Texas  is the leading sheep producing state producing over 175 million
    pounds of lamb and mutton in 1971.  This amount accounted for 17
    percent of U.S.  output (Figure V-2).
    
    California ranks  second in sales of lamb and mutton followed in order
    by Colorado, Wyoming,  South Dakota, Idaho, Utah, Montana,  Iowa
    and Ohio.   These ten states accounted for 70 percent of all lamb and
    mutton production in 1971.
    
    Seventy-seven percent of all production  is concencentrated in ,the western
    half of the U.S.   Increased concentration in  this area  is anticipated.
    Reports of sheep and lambs on feed for  196Z and 1972 show  declining
    inventories  for all states in the eastern  half of the U. S.  States with
    increases in number of head on feed were all located in the  west or
    southwest (Table V- 5). States with increases  were Texas, Wyoming,
    Idaho,  Montana,  Oregon, Arizona, Utah and Nevada.
    
    Employment
    
    The number of people employed in sheep and lamb production  is assumed
    to be a function of the number and size of production units.
    
    Of the  estimated 150,000 people employed on production units, 60,000
    are assumed to be located in the eastern half of the U. S.  The other
    90, 000 persons are assumed to be employed in the west.
                                    V-1Z
    

    -------
                                                        410
            ^—- ' If****' i, 377
            '
    Figxire V-Z,  Quantity of sheep a ad J 'unlit,
    
     Source:  A gr Cultural Statistics , USbA .
    eo in pounds, live .* ei silit basis,  1,000 pounds,  1971
    

    -------
    Table V-5.  Sheep and lambs on feed,  number by states,
        percent of production, ranked by states, U.S.  1972
    State
    Colorado
    Texas
    Iowa
    Nebraska
    South Dakota
    Wyoming
    Minnesota
    Ohio
    Idaho
    California
    Montana
    Oregon
    Kansas
    Arizona
    Utah
    North Dakota
    Illinois
    Michigan
    Mi s s ou ri
    Oklahoma
    New Mexico
    Nevada
    Washington
    Indiana
    Wisconsin
    New York
    Total U.S.
    Source: Agricultural
    — January 1.
    Numb e r
    1962
    570
    240
    474
    377
    257
    105
    248
    198
    <55
    302
    98
    64
    314
    76
    82
    113
    163
    84
    116
    53
    52
    8
    30
    60
    50
    21
    4,250
    Statistics, U. S.D.
    on Feedi/
    1972
    440
    399
    179
    152
    145
    116
    109
    108
    102
    102
    100
    99
    97
    91
    85
    73
    55
    46
    44
    33
    32
    28
    25
    21
    21
    13
    2,715
    A., 1972
    Percent of
    U.S. - 1972
    16.2
    14.7
    6.6
    5.6
    5.3
    4. 3
    4.0
    4.0
    3.8
    3.8
    3.6
    3.6
    3.6
    3.4
    3. 1
    2.7
    2.0
    1.7
    1.6
    1.2
    1.2
    1.0
    0.9
    0.8
    0.8
    0.5
    100.0
    
                               V-14
    

    -------
    Comment
    
    Due to limited time, and also lack of success in obtaining cost of pro-
    duction data,  a financial profile for sheep and lamb production is not
    included in this draft.  If requested, this data will be included in the
    final report.
                                     V-15
    

    -------
                      PART VI:   THE EGG INDUSTRY
    
    
                     I.   EGG INDUSTRY SEGMENTS
    
    
                          A.  Types of Firms
    Since the early 1950's, the market egg industry has undergone rapid
    and at times  revolutionary change.  Emerging is an industry which
    bears little resemblance to that which existed several decades ago.
    
    Large commercial flocks have emerged, increased efficiency has re-
    sulted in increased egg production per bird, egg quality has improved,
    marketing channels have been shortened, and increased coordination has
    occurred involving input-supplier s , egg producers, processing, and
    distribution.   These changes have not occurred uniformly throughout
    the United States as some regions  such as the South, Southwest and
    West have undergone a more rapid evolution than other areas.
    
    Number and Size of Production Units
    
    The  1969 Census of A griculture reported Z79,899 farms with layers.
    This represented a 67 percent decrease since 1 964 when 1, 145, 447
    farms were reported to have layers. _   Decreases in the number
    of farms occurred in those farms with flocks of under 10,000 birds
    (Table VI-1).  Farms  with larger flocks increased in number.
    
    During this five year period there were  significant increases in con-
    centration of birds in  larger flocks.  The number of farms with over
    10, 000 birds increased from 5,4l4to7,175.   The percent of birds
    controlled by these larger producers increased from 39 to 67 percent.
    In 1969 two and one-half percent of all farms with layers controlled two-
    thirds of all birds.
    
                                              Percent of layers in Flocks
                                              Under               Over
                                              10,000             10,000
    
                 1964                          61                  39
                 1969                          33                  67
    _'  Part of this decrease may be explained by the fact that the 1964
        census included all farms and the 1969 census included only those
        farms with gross incomes of $2,500 or more.
                                      VI-1
    

    -------
      Table VI -1. Number of farms with layers and percent of layers,
                        by size, 1964 and 1969, U.S.
    19691/
    Size/Birds
    
    
    
    1,
    3,
    10,
    20,
    50,
    100
    1 - 99
    100 - 399
    400 - 1,599
    600 - 3,195
    200 - 9,999
    000 - 19,999
    000 - 49,999
    000 - 99,999
    ,000 +
    Total
    Number
    Farms
    166,591
    72,957
    21,525
    3,630
    8,021
    4,047
    2,238
    565
    325
    279,899
    Percent
    Farms
    59-
    26.
    7.
    1.
    2.
    1.
    0.
    0.
    0.
    100.
    5
    1
    7
    3
    9
    4
    8
    2
    1
    0
    1964^
    Percent Number Percent
    layers Farms Farms
    2.
    5.
    5.
    3.
    17.
    19-
    22.
    11.
    14.
    100.
    0
    1
    3
    1
    5
    3
    1
    2
    4
    0
    832,790 72.7
    223,080 19-5
    62,314 5.5
    9,540 0.8
    12,309 1-1
    3,466 0.3
    1,484 0.1
    329
    135
    1,145,447 100.0
    
    
    Percent
    layers
    7.
    12.
    12.
    6.
    21.
    14.
    12.
    5.
    6.
    100.
    6
    6
    4
    8
    7
    4
    7
    7
    7
    0
    Source: _  1969 Agricultural Census, Farms with gross incomes of
               $2, 500 or mote,
            I/ 1964 Agricultural Census.  All farms.
                                  Vl-2
    

    -------
    Volume of Marketings
    
    The average number of layers on farms has exceeded 300 million
    birds during the past eight years.  In  1965 there were 301 million
    birds on farms.  The number on farms increased to 319 million in
    1971 and then decreased to 307 million in 1972.
    
                                               Average No.  of Layers
                                                     (1,000's)
    
                         1972                       307,090
                         1971                       314,805
                         1970                       312,922
                         1969                       306,281
                         1968                       309,824
                         1967                       313,720
                         1966                       303,833
                         1965                       301,055
    
    The decline in layer numbers since 1971 was partially offset by in-
    creased productivity of layers.  Average number of layers decreased
    by 2.4 percent while shell egg production decreased by  only one percent.
    Increased productivity resulted from reduced mortality of pullets  prior
    to and after entering the laying flock and also improved health and vigor
    of layers.  The primary factor influencing productivity  was the continued
    and increased use of Marek's vaccine.
    
    The volume of eggs  sold from farms has not changed significantly during
    the past seven years.  In 1972 farmers sold 5, 898 million dozen eggs,
    an increase of less than one percent since 1965.
    
                                               Eggs Produced
                                               Million dozens
                          1972                      5,898
                          1971                      5,987
                          1970                      5,853
                          1969                      5,629
                          1968                      5,680
                          1967                      5,777
                          1966                      5,517
                          1965                      5,463
                                     VI-3
    

    -------
    The value of eggs sold equalled $1,832 million in 1972 and represented
    3. 5 percent of total farm income.
    
    The significance of eggs as a source of farm income varies greatly
    by states.  In Connecticut,  Maine and New Hampshire, egg sales account
    for over twenty  percent of farm income.  In Alabama, Massachusetts
    and Georgia,  eggs contribute between ten and thirteen percent of farm
    income. In other egg producing states, eggs  contribute less than ten
    percent of farm income.
    
    
    Age of Production Facilities
    
    There are no known studies pertaining to the age of houses for layers.
    •Therefore,  estimates by regions are made on the basis of shifts in
    egg production by areas, rates  of growth by states and types-of manage-
    ment systems used in production.
    
    The average life of a layer house is estimated to be twenty years.  In
    areas where the climate is harsh the life expectancy maybe greater
    due to construction of better facilities for warding off the effects of
    extremely cold  temperatures.  These facilities  require larger capital
    expenditures and, therefore, longer use before being replaced.
    
    Egg production  has shifted geographically during the past decade.  The
    South, from the Carolina's to Arkansas, has  experienced a rapid growth
    in the number of layers.  Also  growth has occurred in Maine and Cali-
    fornia.  To accomplish this growth construction of new laying houses
    must have occurred.
    
    In other traditional production areas of the United States,  such as New
    York, Pennsylvania and the Corn Belt states, egg production has been
    declining.   With production declining, we can assume that few new replace-
    ment houses are being built and that most houses have been fully de-
    preciated and are approaching obsolesence.
    
    If these assumptions are correct, we can conclude that the average age
    of layer houses  is lowest in the  South Atlantic, Mid-South and the states
    of Maine and California.  Average age of houses in these areas is esti-
    mated to be  5-10 years.   Housing in the Corn Belt and New York area
    is estimated to average 15 years of age.
                                  VI-4
    

    -------
    Location of Major Production Segments
    
    California  is the leading egg producing state with over 39 million layers,
    representing 12. 8 percent of all birds in the United States.  Of the ten
    leading states,  six are located in the South or Southwest and include
    Georgia, Arkansas, North Carolina, Alabama, Texas and Florida.
    (Figure VI-1).
    
                                               Percent of
                  State                      U.S.  Layers
    
                  California                     12.8
                  Georgia                        8. 1
                  Arkansas                       5.4
                  North Carolina                  4. 9
                  Pennsylvania                   4. 9
                  Indiana                         4. 2
                  Alabama                       4. 1
                  Texas                          3.9
                  Florida                         3.9
                  Minnesota                      3. 6
    Egg production has shifted geographically during the past seven years
    with production being concentrated in the South, California,  Maine and
    Indiana (Table  VI-2).  Major increases in layer numbers,  since  1965,
    have occurred  in Florida, Arkansas, Georgia, Maine,  the Carolina's,
    Alabama, California, and Indiana.  Declines occurred  in other leading
    states  such as  Iowa, Wisconsin, Illinois,  Minnesota, Ohio, Texas,
    New York, Michigan, and Pennsylvania.  Major egg producing states
    which had increases in layer numbers since 1965 are as follows:
    
                                             Percent change in
                   State                   layer number, 1965 - 1972
    
                   Florida                        57
                  Arkansas                      49
                   Georgia                       32
                   Maine                         31
                   South Carolina                 27
                   North Carolina                22
                  Alabama                      20
                   California                     20
                   Indiana                        13
                   Mississippi                     4
                   Missouri                       2
    
                                       VI-5
    

    -------
    •<
    i—*
    t
                     Figure vi. i.  CHICKENS ON HAND, THREE MONTHS OLD AND OVER, 1969
                              I
                               \   :
                                                        - \   -_^_.	^   -.    .
                                                       :   V    ^:-/V^--\jU'"J-
    ™*t- • I r . . "•-»••»•-' -^^JIT, ' \ ~\ •
    C ' ••- !-- . '. .' R1--S: .-••(•
    - lr-\ 	 l •- . ."' /••?•• \ (_^-rr
    x\ ' -.-'. r.;^-""
    V /--x • . >• ;- ••-•^
    \ ./"
    t. J SHKC • C€«SBJ am
    ^'-}
    V'
    j*V-
    T*.
    • %
    «••••»
    •ft". '
    •»
    i DOT -- m,tw «M
    41 STITt TOTM. • JH.IBMM
                         Source;  Pouitry and Egg Situation, Economic Research Service, U.S. Department of
    
    
                                 Agriculture, November 1972.
    

    -------
     Table VI-2. Number of layers, by states, ranked in declining order
                            of significance,  1972
    State
    California
    Georgia
    Arkansas
    North Carolina
    Pennsylvania
    Indiana
    A labama
    Texas
    Florida
    Minnesota
    
    Mis sissippi
    Ohio
    New York
    lowA
    Illinois
    Missouri
    Michigan
    Maine
    Wisconsin
    South Carolina
    
    United States
    Numb e r
    layers
    39,
    24,
    16,
    15,
    15,
    12,
    12,
    12,
    12,
    10,
    171,
    10,
    10,
    9,
    9,
    7,
    6,
    6,
    5,
    5,
    5,
    78,
    307,
    201
    754
    519
    172
    081
    865
    552
    115
    075
    917
    231
    424
    158
    903
    814
    804
    661
    621
    902
    806
    757
    850
    090
    Percent of
    U.S.
    12.
    8.
    K
    4r
    4,
    4.
    4,
    3.
    O .
    J t
    55.
    3.
    3.
    -> .
    3 „
    2.
    "1
    ^
    J. ,
    1,
    I.
    25,
    
    8
    1
    4
    9
    9
    2
    i
    9
    Q
    .">
    8
    i
    
    ^
    J
    5
    '>
    t.
    9
    r.
    Q
    f
    
    Percent change,
    1965-1972
    20
    32
    49
    22
    - 3
    13
    20
    - 5
    57
    -}
    ~ I
    
    4
    - 6
    - 5
    -41
    - 7
    2
    - 4
    31
    -13
    ?"
    
    -
    Source:  USDA, SRS
                                    VI -7
    

    -------
    Level of Technology and Efficiency
    
    The commercial egg industry must be regarded as an  industry which
    is innovative and relatively efficient in the use of resources.  New
    technology is rapidly adopted,  particularly by larger producers,  as a
    means to reduce costs in a highly competitive industry.
    
    Poultry houses are engineered for minimizing labor requirements in
    feeding,  cleaning, as well as egg collection.  Houses are also designed
    for specific climatic conditions.
    
    Methods  of handling layers has changed drastically during the past half
    decade.  Data from trade sources show a shift from traditional floor-
    litter systems of handling birds to the use of cage or wire-type systems.
    It is estimated that 75 percent of all layers in 1972 were housed in cage  or
    wire-type houses compared to only 44 percent in  1965.  Use of cage systems
    has grown most rapidly in the growth areas.
    
    Adoption of new health practices has been accelerating.  An example is
    the use of Marek's vaccine.   The time span from the inception of the
    vaccine to widespread use was about one  year.  The resultant effect
    was decreased mortality and increased productivity per layer.
    
    Size of flocks has  been increasing, mortality rate has  decreased,
    eggs per hen have increased, quality of eggs has  improved, and the
    labor requirements  per hen have declined.  All the factors are indica-
    tive of increasing efficiency resulting from widepsread use  of new
    technology.
    
    Perhaps  the best measure of increased efficiency are the changes
    which have occurred in the farm to retailer  price spreads.  In 1955
    this spread equalled 18. 1 cents per dozen.   By 1969 it had decreased
    to 9.0 cents.,  Without a progressive industry, consumers v/ould  have
    paid 9.0 cents more per dozen for all eggs consumed.
    
    Level of Integration-Coordination
    
    The egg  industry has evolved from small farm flock oriented production
    systems to large scale commercial production units.   Three decades ago
    production was concentrated in small flocks with surplus eggs being sold
    to local buying stations, stores or consumers.  Producers made all
    management decisions relative to feeding programs, types of chicks
    to buy, remedies for disease control or prevention, and other manage-
    ment practices.
                                    VI-8
    

    -------
    As time passed, technological advances were made in disease  control
    and feeding practices.   These advances  coupled with improved trans-
    portation,  and communication made larger production units more feasi-
    ble.   At this stage many functions formerly performed by producers left
    the farm and specialization developed in feed milling,  hatching, and
    egg distribution.  Producers relied more and more upon outside sources
    for production inputs and for egg distribution.
    
    Then as some production units  reached larger scales, many began to
    integrate both backward and forward.  Producers established their  own
    feed milling facilities ,  hatcheries, breeding flocks ,  egg proce ssing
    facilities and  distribution programs.
    
    The  industry today is a  composite of  completely integrated units to
    producers  who remain  relatively independent.  The trend is  toward
    greater vertical integration and/or coordination.
    
    The  percent of table eggs produced by owner-integrators increased
    from 1.5 percent in 1955 to 20.0 percent in 1970. _'  A corresponding
    increase occurred with  eggs  produced under production contracts. —
    Contract marketing of eggs has  increased slightly from 12, 5 percent
    in 1955 to  15.0 percent  in the 1970's.  Percent of eggs from independent
    producers  has decreased rapidly accounting for only 45.0 percent of
    all eggs in 1970.1/
                             Percent of Market Eggs Produced By:
                     Owner       Contract      Contract     Independent
                   Integrator     Producer     Marketing      Producers
    
            1955       1.5          0.5          12.5            85.5
    
            1970      20.0         20.0          15.0            45.0
    
    The extent of integration varies by region of the United States.  Egg
    production from  owner- Integra ted operations and contract production
    is most significant in the South Atlantic,  South  Central, and the West.
    —  Owner-integrator controls  via ownership all factors of production
       and processing.
    £.' Production contracts.  Includes  all contractional arrangements between
       an integrator and grower including:  (a)  supplying of production inputs by
       a contractor; and (2) payments of a stipulated amount per dozen to a
       grower who  has  ownership of production facilities.
    £/Marketing Channels for Eggs, G-M. Rogers,  Marketing Economics Div. ,
       U.S.D.A. , Marketing & Transportation  Situation, May, 1973.
                                   VI-9
    

    -------
                              Percent of 1969 Market Egg Supply From:
                                            Owner            Contract
           Area                           Integrators         Producers
    
           North Atlantic                     11.5               16.8
           East North Central                 8.0               11.5
           West North Central                 4.7                5.6
           South Atlantic                     19.2               24.1
           South Central                     32.3               33.5
           West                              39.0               13.7
           United States                      19.2               19.0
    
           Source:  Vertical and Horizontal Integration in the Market Egg
                    Industry, 1955-69, ERS, USDA, ERS 477.
    
    Level of Diversification
    
    The majority of egg  producers are specialized units with specialization
    increasing as flock size increases. —  Flocks of 20, 000 birds or more
    require a  full time commitment of an entrepreneur.  As flock sizes
    have increased, egg production has moved from being a supplementary
    farm enterprise to a full time occupation.
    
    In the major egg producing states of New England, New York, the  South
    and West egg production is a specialized  enterprise.  In portions of the
    Midwest some producers  still have small flocks to supplement farm in-
    come.   These numbers, however, are  rapidly decreasing.
    
    With the exception of the Midwest,  most egg producers  have few farm
    alternatives other than egg production.  In most areas  of the South
    and New England, the  topography of the land limits  row crop production.
    Also land  bases are  relatively small preventing expansion into livestock
    production which require  larger  acreage. The best alternative egg pro-
    ducers have in these areas  is probably off-farm employment.
    
    In the corn belt areas  egg production has been a diversified enterprise
    particularly with farm flocks  of 5,000 or less  birds.  Having other farming
    alternatives, is one  of the factors that has led to the decrease in egg
    production in the midwest.  The  comparative advantage of row crops
    and/or livestock, and  larger land basis,  has  resulted in many midwest
    farmers discontinuing egg production.
    —  1969  Census of Agriculture.
                                   VI-10
    

    -------
               B.  Number of Plants and Employment by Segments
    In 1969 the Census of Agriculture reported 279,899 farms with layers,
    These  farms were further classified using the number of layers  as a
    measurement of size.
                  Size of Flock                       Number of Farms
    
                         1'-  99                             166,591
                       100 -  399                            72,957
                       400 -  1,599                          21,525
                     1,600 -  3,195                           3,630
                     3,200 -  9,999                           8,021
                    10,000 -  19,999                          4,047
                    20,000 -  49,999                          2,238
                    50,000 -  99,999                            565
                  100,000+                                    325
                       Total                                279,899
    Statistics pertaining to the number of people  employed in egg production
    units is not available,.  Therefore, employment was estimated using size
    of flocks as the  criterion for determining Labor requirements.
    
    Labor  requirements for caring for flocks with I. ss than 400 birds is
    assumed to be insignificant.  Flocks of thi« size are primarily located
    in the Midwest and used as  a source of supply for  home  consumption.
    
    To estimate the labor requirements for all flocks  exceeding 400 birds,
    the assumption was made that  producers sell eggs to processors in case
    lots, with all grading and cartoning being done by  egg processors.
    
    Next the assumption was made that a  25,000  bird flock would require
    the full time efforts of one man.  Labor  requirements for larger flocks
    were prorated using a 25, 000 bird flock as a norm.  Fa rms with flocks
    under 25,000 birds -were assumed to require one full time man.
                                     VI-11
    

    -------
    Size
    Flock I'
       1,000
       2,400
       6,500
     15,000
     35,000
     75,000
    135,000
    Number
     Farms
    
    21,525
     3,630
     8,021
     4,047
     2,238
       565
       325
    40,351
    Labor Required
      Per Farm —
        1.0
        1.0
        1.0
        1.0
        1.4
        3.0
        5.4
    Total
    Labor
    
    21, 525
     3,630
     8,021
     4,047
     3,376
     1,695
     1,755
    44,049
    —  Midpoint of range used by Census of Agriculture
    —  Units of full time labor required per flock
    An estimated 44,049 people are employed on 40,351 units and supply
    93 percent of all table eggs.  The remaining eggs are supplied by small
    farm flocks for  which it is difficult to estimate employment.
    
    Of the  44,049  people employed in egg production, 40,351 are estimated
    to be individual  producers and  does not include family labor.   The other
    3,698 people are assumed to be hired labor.
               C.  Relationship of Segments to Total Industry
    Number of Production Units
    
    In 1969 the Agricultural Census reported 279, 899 farmers with layers
    (Table VI-3 ).   These farms were scattered throughout the United
    States •with all states having  some flocks.
    
    Of the total number  of farms, 5.4 percent had flocks of 3,200 or more
    birds. These 15, 196 production units controlled 85 percent of all layers.
    Concentration of layers in these  larger flocks  has been increasing and
    represents the  relevant segments of the egg industry.
    
    Georgia has the largest number of farms with  flocks of 3,200 or more
    birds (Table VI-3 ).   North Carolina ranks second, followed in order
    by California, Arkansas, Alabama,  Ohio and Pennsylvania.
                                   VI -12
    

    -------
    Table VI-3.Numbe r of farms with layers and number of farms with
                  flocks  of 3,200 or more layers,  1969
    State
    Georgia
    North Carolina
    California
    A rkansas
    Alabama
    Ohio
    Pennsylvania
    Indiana
    Texas
    Minnesota
    Iowa
    Florida
    Michigan
    New York
    Illinois
    South Ca rolina
    Maine
    Missouri
    Mis sissippi
    New Jersey
    Tennessee
    A rizona
    Connecticut
    Wisconsin
    Virginia
    Washington
    Louisiana
    Kansas
    Kentucky
    Massachusetts
    Maryland
    New Hampshire
    Oklahoma
    South Dakota
    Oregon
    West Virginia
    Utah
    Nebraska
    Idaho
    Delaware
    Farms with 3, 200
    or More Layers
    1,497
    1,059
    994
    951
    935
    814
    789
    756
    521
    487
    455
    433
    437
    411
    350
    313
    298
    296
    296
    275
    265
    264
    218
    206
    197
    173
    171
    154
    150
    139
    113
    102
    97
    92
    81
    69
    59
    48
    35
    35
    All Farms
    with Layers
    4,448
    9,449
    2,805
    3,837
    3,845
    9,855
    7, 961
    8,039
    14,462
    15,955
    26,450
    1,526
    4, 964
    3, 314
    14,863
    2,653
    538
    15, 980
    4,009
    856
    9,068
    315
    b34
    14, 304
    6, 177
    1, 826
    3,261
    13, 184
    10,504
    497
    1,725
    305
    7,970
    12,034
    1,750
    1,705
    712
    17,024
    2, 113
    269
                                      VI-13
    

    -------
                          Table VI-3.(continued)
    State
    Colorado
    Monta na
    Rhode Island
    Vermont
    New Mexico
    North Dakota
    Wyoming
    Nevada
    Total
    Farms with 3,200
    or More Layers
    33
    31
    27
    21
    18
    14
    7
    --
    15, 196
    All Farms
    with Layers
    3,590
    4,367
    86
    416
    931
    7,651
    1,504
    268
    279,899
    Source:  1969 Census of Agriculture.  Farms with gross incomes of
             $2, 500 or more.
                                    VI-14
    

    -------
    Production
    
    Egg production is highly correlated with the average number of layers
    on farm.  Therefore, the relationship of segments to the total industry
    will be analyzed by using average number of layers on farm.
    
    There is considerable variation, by states, in the percentage of layers
    controlled by different size  segments of layers.   In the ten leading egg
    producing states,  concentration of birds in flocks of 50, 000 or more
    varies from a high of 66 percent in California to a low of 13.6 percent
    in Minnesota (Table VI-4).  Generally the greatest concentration of
    layers in large flocks are found in those states which have recently emerged
    as major egg producing centers.  States included are Alabama, Texas,
    Florida, Georgia,  Arkansas,  North Carolina and California.
    
    
    Employment
    
    Egg production up to a certain size layer flock is primarily a family-
    type of operation.  The  concensus  of trade people is that the average
    farmer with family labor can  care for a layer ilock of 25 , 000 birds .
    This assumes he sell eggs in  cases to a processor and does not  grade
    or carton eggs on farm.
    
    As  the size of flocks increase by units  of 25,000  birds it is assumed
    one additional man will need to be  hired.  Und^r  this assumption,  a
    100, 000 bird flock would require four full time employees.
    
    An estimated 44,000 people are employed on farms with  layers.  This
    number  can essentially be allocated among states relative Lo the per-
    centage  of larger farms lo.cated in each of these  states.
                                      VI-15
    

    -------
    Table VI-4. Number of farms and percent of layers, by size, ten leading states, 1969
    
    California
    No. farms
    Percent farms
    Percent layers
    Georgia
    No. farms
    Percent farms
    Percent layers
    Arkansas
    No. farms
    Percent farms
    Percent layers
    North Carolina
    No. farms
    Percent farms
    Percent layers
    Pennsylvania
    No. farms
    Percent farms
    Percent layers
    1-99
    
    1,569
    55.9
    . 1
    
    2,682
    60.3
    .2
    
    2,659
    69.3
    .3
    
    7,211
    76.3
    1.3
    
    2,731
    34.3
    .8
    100-
    399
    
    70
    2.5
    . 1
    
    104
    2.3
    . 1
    
    134
    3.5
    . 1
    
    687
    7.3
    .7
    
    2,076
    26. 1
    3.2
    400-
    1,599
    
    95
    3.4
    .2
    
    77
    1.7
    .3
    
    44
    1. 1
    .2
    
    337
    3.6
    1.8
    
    1,870
    23.4
    10.9
    1,600-
    3, 199
    
    77
    2.7
    .4
    
    88
    1.9
    .8
    
    49
    1.3
    .7
    
    155
    1.6
    2.6
    
    495
    6.2
    8.5
    3,200-
    9,999
    
    257
    9.2
    3.8
    
    641
    14.4
    15.4
    
    490
    12.8
    17.2
    
    609
    6.4
    25.3
    
    461
    5.8
    20.0
    10,000-
    19,999
    
    271
    9.7
    9.2
    
    498
    11.2
    25.3
    
    268
    7.0
    18.8
    
    291
    3.0
    26. 1
    
    210
    2.6
    20.6
    20,000-
    49,999
    
    282
    10.0
    20.5
    
    267
    6.0
    28. 1
    
    143
    3.7
    22.0
    
    127
    1.4
    23.9
    
    94
    1.2
    19.7
    50,000-
    99,999
    
    103
    3.7
    15.9
    
    60
    1.9
    13.4
    
    34
    .9
    11.4
    
    24
    .3
    9.6
    
    17
    .2
    6.4
    100,000+
    
    81
    2.9
    49.8
    
    31
    .8
    16.4
    
    16
    .4
    29.3
    
    8
    . 1
    8.7
    
    7
    . 1
    9.9
    Total
    
    2,805
    100
    100
    
    4,448
    100
    100
    
    3,837
    100
    100
    
    9,449
    100
    100
    
    7,961
    100
    100
    

    -------
                                             Table VI-4.  (continued)
    
    Indiana
    No. farms
    Percent farms
    Percent layers
    Alabama
    No. farms
    Percent farms
    Percent layers
    Texas
    No. farms
    Percent farms
    Percent layers
    Florida
    No . fa rm s
    Percent farms
    Percent layers
    Minnesota
    No. farms
    Percent farms
    Percent layers
    1-99
    
    3,869
    48.1
    1.2
    
    2,574
    66.9
    . 5
    
    11,093
    76.7
    2.6
    
    957
    62.7
    . 1
    
    4,666
    29.2
    2
    100-
    399
    
    2,435
    30.3
    4
    
    154
    4.0
    .2
    
    2, 124
    14.7
    3.0
    
    45
    2.9
    . 1
    
    7 , 640
    47.9
    17.7
    400-
    1,599
    
    770
    9.6
    4.6
    
    110
    2.9
    .7
    
    561
    3.9
    3.2
    
    52
    3.4
    .3
    
    2,943
    18.4
    19.6
    1,600-
    3, 199
    
    209
    2.6
    4.4
    
    72
    2.0
    1.4
    
    163
    1. 1
    3.0
    
    39
    2.6
    .6
    
    219
    1.4
    5. 1
    3,200-
    9,999
    
    428
    5.3
    21.4
    
    524
    13.6
    25.0
    
    227
    1.6
    10,7
    
    102
    6.7
    4.7
    
    350
    2.2
    23. 1
    10,000-
    19,999
    
    186
    2.3
    20.8
    
    262
    6.8
    26.0
    
    129
    .9
    13, 8
    
    117
    7.7
    12,0
    
    104
    .6
    15, 0
    20,000-
    49,999
    
    118
    1.5
    27.0
    
    106
    2.8
    21.8
    
    118
    .8
    26.8
    
    154
    10. 1
    33.5
    
    20
    . 1
    4.9
    50,000-
    99,999
    
    18
    .2
    • 9. 1
    
    32
    .8
    14.9
    
    30
    .2
    16. 1
    
    38
    2.5
    17.4
    
    6
    „ 1
    2.9
    100,000+
    
    6
    . 1
    7.5
    
    11
    .2
    9.5
    
    17
    . 1
    20.8
    
    22
    1.4
    31. 2
    
    7
    . 1
    9.7
    Total
    
    8,039
    100
    100
    
    3,845
    100
    100
    
    14,462
    100
    100
    
    1,526
    100
    100
    
    15,955
    100
    100
    Source:  1969 Agricultural Census:  Farms with gross sales of 2, 500 or more.
    

    -------
                II.   EGG INDUSTRY FINANCIAL PROFILE
    The commercial egg industry is characterized by operations with 9, 000-
    bird flocks or greater.  The industry is primarily concerned with the
    production of eggs for retail sale  and home table consumption.  We are
    including for purpose of comparison of financial profiles flocks of 3,  000
    or more birds.
    
    At this time we  are limiting our analysis to first cycle production, with-
    out consideration of molting or other means of extending the useful pro-
    ductivity of hens.
    
    It is assumed that there are sufficient numbers of producers and pur-
    chasers in the egg industry that no firm or operation can affect the prices
    paid or received by either in the overall industry.
                          A.  Plants by Segments
    
    Flocks with 3, 000 or fewer birds are basically a farm operation producing
    a very insignificant  portion of the total eggs produced (although significant
    in number).  These  operations typically provide eggs for home consumption
    with surplus production  being sold.  These operations are also character-
    ized by very low levels of investment, and very limited use of labor savings
    technology.
    
    Our primary study is  directed at three different types of operations with
    flock sizes  ranging from 8,700 to 18,800 birds.  The three operations are
    defined as follows:
    
            1.   Flocks of  8, 780 birds housed in conventional floor systems.
           2.   Flocks of  9, 70Z birds housed in manual cage systems.
           3.   Flocks of  18, 886 birds housed in automatic cage systems.
    
    All three of these operations are assumed to be operated exclusively by
    family labor.  Diseconomies of scale exist when size of flock involved
    exceeds  the capacity of family labor to operate the operation   Operations
    of such capacity do not represent a significant number of the total oper-
    ations in the industry.
    
    In all three operations utilization is  assumed  to be 100 percent.
                                    VI-18
    

    -------
    Egg Industry Profitability
    
    Commercial egg producers that are included in our study showed after-
    tax return on sales from 7 to 10 percent (Table VI-5).  After-tax ROI
    is estimated at between 33.7 percent to 51.9 percent.   The high  level of
    these ratios may be attributed to the  low level of investment as compared
    to the level of sales.  Earnings are very sensitive to  changes in  feed costs
    and retail egg prices.  A one percent drop in the price  of eggs results  in
    an average 7.5 percent drop in pre-tax income.  Similar effects  may be
    expected for changes in feed prices.
    
    There is a significant relationship  between the level of  labor saving
    machinery used and the dollar profits accruing to the  owner, although
    ROI is declining as dollar returns are increasing.   Family labor in the
    three commercial units remains constant  so that there  are significant
    increases in dollar returns to owners for their efforts by using labor
    saving machinery.
    
    Annual Cash Flow
    
    Estimated annual cash flow (after tax income plus depreciation) and cash
    flow on average fixed investment are shown  in Tables VT-6 and VI-7 for selected
    model operations.  Depreciation schedules for operations  indicated are
    based on a useful life of 10 years for building and 10 years for equipment.
    
    Cash flows like profitability are highly variable  and dependent upon egg
    price and feed costs.  In our model operation data on the three commercial
    size ope rations ,  depreciation composed from 21.8 percent to 31.7 pe rcent
    of total cash flows.
    
    The majority of the  egg producers  apply their annual  cash flow two-fold,
    one to retire  government insured and other loans and  secondly, to live on.
    The majority of farmer type  growers typically do not attempt to  reinvest
    depreciation and earnings nor accumulate  them to  replace worn  out facilities,
    but rather apply these funds to  pay for the day to day  expenses of living and
    maintaining a family.
    
    Market (Salvage) Value of Assets
    
    The salvage value of the assets in the commercial egg industry are
    limited to the value  that an individual producer would place in  the
    physical structure (building) for alternative  use, perhaps  15 percent
    of original investment.
                                     VI-19
    

    -------
                  Table VI-5.  Estimated pre-tax income and rate of return on average invested capital and after-
                                         tax return on sales for egg producersby size of flock,  1971
    
    
                                                                  Size of Flock
    Financial Measure	3,000	8,780	9,702	18, 886
    
    
    Pre-tax net income                      $1,530          $6,000         $6,762           $11,011
    
    
    Pre-tax ROI* (%)                          42.3            51.5          66.6              43.3
    
    
    After-tax ROI* (%)                        33.0            40.2          51-9              33.7
    
    
    After-tax return on sales (%)                7.0             9-5          10.1               8.5
    
    
    
    */ Average return on fixed investment calculated by financial statement method.
    tN)
    O
    

    -------
                        Table VI-6.  Estimated cash flow for egg producers by' size of flock,  1971
                                                                  Size of Flock
    Financial Measure                      3,000            8,780         9,702            18,886
    
    
    Annual cash flow ($)                    1,734            6,471         $6,739           12,593
    
    
    Cash flow on average fixed
      investment  (%)                         48.0             55.6          66.4              49.5
    

    -------
    Taole VI -7.   Estimated cash flow for egg producers, by size of flock,  1971
    
    Utilization (%)
    Annual Output
    Sales
    Variable Expenses
    Feed
    Other
    Fixed Expenses
    Cash Earnings
    Depreciation
    Interest
    Pre-tax Income
    Excluding Family Labor
    Cash Earnings
    Depreciation
    Interest
    Pre-tax Income
    3,000
    100
    
    16,974
    9,126
    7,779
    54
    15
    540
    -525
    2,070
    540
    1,530
    8,780
    100
    
    49,342
    26,892
    16,310
    555
    5,585
    1,791
    1,713
    2,081
    9,504
    1,791
    1,713
    6,000
    9,702
    100
    
    52,049
    27,932
    17,689
    480
    5,948
    1,465
    1,687
    2,796
    9,914
    1,465
    1,687
    6,762
    18,886
    100
    
    101,319
    54,373
    30,690
    2,554
    13,702
    4,004
    2,662
    7,036
    17,677
    4,004
    2,662
    11,011
    

    -------
    Feeding equipment, cages and egg collection and storage  equipment
    being highly specialized in nature has zero salvage value.
    
    Buildings comprise approximately 50 to 60 percent of total investment
    in the conventional floor  systems, 45 to 55 percent in manual cage
    systems and 35 to 40 percent in mechanical cage systems.
    
    Capital Structure
    
    The commercial egg industry 'generally requires a low level of invest-
    ment for each dollar of sales.  In the commercial egg industry the ratio
    is between $2. 50 to $3. 50 depending upon the type of operation involved.
    
    The capital requirements are indicated in Table VI-8 and as can be
    seen, the amounts  of capital do  not appear  to be materially large in
    amount. Both fixed asset and working  capital requirements a re  a
    function of the number of birds to be  handled.
    Cost Structure
    
    
    Fixed expenses are defined as those that do not vary in relationship
    to output.  These include:
    
           Depreciation
           Interest on Buildings  and Equipment
           Taxes and Insurance
    
    Variable expenses are those  expenses that do vary in relationship to
    output.   These include:
    
           Feed
           Hen depreciation
           Medication, sanitation
           Miscellaneous
    
    The  specific breakdown of  these costs are presented in Table VI-9.
    
    Table VT-lOshows the relationship between sales and various cost com-
    ponents.  Raw materials (hen depreciation and feed) compose the majority
    of costs,  representing 77 percent of sales for commercial operations.
    Other cost components are relatively insignificant in amount when compared
    to raw material costs.
    
    For  this  reason even minor changes in raw material costs will cause
    very significant changes  in the total cost structure of the operation.
    
                                    VI-23
    

    -------
                       Table VI-8-  Estimated replacement value and working capital requirements for egg
                                           producers, by size of flock, 1971
    
    
                                                                 Size of Flock
     Capital Component                      3,000            8,780         9,702            18,886
     Replacement value of facilities
      and equipment ($)                      5,400           17,911        14,650            40,038
    
    
     Net working capital!/($)                   912            2,689         2,793              5,437
    
    
     Replacement value of total
      assets ($)                              6,312           20,600        17,443            45,475
     — Net working capital = current assets - current liabilities
       Current assets  = 10% of feed costs + hen depreciation
       Current liabilities = hen depreciation
    I
    INJ
    

    -------
            Table Vl-9.    Total investment and annual cost of producing eggs, by size of flock,  1971
                                                                           Size of Flock
                                                3,000!^
                                  9,
    Investment Costs
       Building and Equipment
    
    Annual Fixed Costs
       Depreciation
       Interest on Building & E
       Taxes and Insurance
       Total Fixed Costs
    
    Annual Variable Costs
       Feed
       Hen Depreciation
       Interest on Operating Capital
       Medication & Sanitation
       Miscellaneous
       Labor  (family)
       Total Variable Costs
    
    Total Costs
    
    Total Costs Excluding Farm labor
    $  5,400
    $17,911
    540
    quipment
    54
    594
    9,126
    5,238
    pital
    162
    324
    2,055
    16,905
    17,499
    m labor 15,444
    1 ,
    1,
    
    3,
    26,
    11,
    
    
    
    3,
    43,
    47,
    43,
    791
    063
    555
    409
    892
    106
    650
    714
    571
    919
    852
    261
    342
    $14,650
                                  18.886.2/
    $40,038
    1 ,465
    967
    480
    2,912
    27,932
    12,351
    720
    830
    569
    3,966
    46,341
    49,280
    45,314
    4,
    1,
    2,
    7,
    54,
    24,
    1 ,
    1,
    1,
    3,
    86,
    94,
    90,
    004
    261
    554
    819
    373
    043
    401
    564
    108
    975
    464
    283
    308
    _' Costs derived from various Iowa State  University,  Farm Management Extension
    2/ Source: Cost and Returns Analysis for Independent  Commercial Egg Producers in Georgia,  G. C. Lance, College
               of Agriculture Experiment Stations, Research Bulletin 113, June,  1972.
               - Flocks of 8,780 are housed in conventional floor systems
               - Flocks of 9.702 are housed in manual cage systems
               - Flocks of 18,886 are housed in automatic cage systems
               - All systems are assumed to be operated by owner with no hir^d  labor.
    

    -------
                            Table VI- 10. Estimated costs for egg producers, by size of flock,  1971
    I—I
    I
    
    
    
    
    3, 000
    Item
    Sales-
    Raw materials-
    Direct operating costs
    Indirect operating costs
    Depreciation
    Interest
    Total before-tax cost
    $
    16,974
    14, 364
    486
    54
    540
    -0-
    15,444
    %
    100.0
    84.6
    2.8
    .3
    3.2
    
    90.9
    
    
    
    8,780
    *t O/
    49,
    37,
    1,
    
    1,
    1,
    43,
    342
    998
    285
    555
    791
    713
    342
    100.
    77.
    2.
    1.
    3.
    3.
    87.
    0
    0
    6
    1
    6
    5
    8
    
    
    
    9,702
    $
    52, 049
    40,283
    1,399
    480
    1,465
    1,687
    45,314
    
    
    18, 886
    Of d? of
    100.0
    77.4
    2.7
    .9
    2.8
    3.2
    87.0
    101,
    78,
    2,
    2,
    4,
    2,
    90,
    319
    416
    672
    554
    004
    662
    308
    100.0
    77.4
    2.6
    2.5
    3.9
    2.7
    89. 1
          —  Based on price of 31. l£/dozen.
    
          —  Includes feed and hen depreciation.
    

    -------
                   B.   Ability to Finance New Investment
    
    As indicated earlier,  virtually all of the internally generated cash flow
    is applied to pay off loans and to live on.  However new financial invest-
    ment would generally not be difficult to generate  considering the avail-
    ability of funds from government insured loans, local  bank mortgage
    financing or from feed manufacturing firms.
    
    The  availability of these funds would generally not be  tied to the
    profitability of the operation..
                                  VI-27
    

    -------
                   PART VII:   THE BROILER INDUSTRY
    
                   I.   BROILER INDUSTRY SEGMENTS
    
    
                           A.   Types of Firms
    The broiler industry in the United States has evolved from an industry
    in which production originated from a multitude of small farm flocks
    to the present system of  large production units.  The bulk of commercial
    production today is concentrated on less than 29,000 production units
    with each unit averaging  about 100, 000 birds annually m 1972.  Growers
    have used broilers as a  means to supplement farm income.  The present
    trend is toward larger units requiring full-time employment of farm labor.
    
    Broiler production today is a highly integrated system (figure VII-1).
    Integrators generally have their own hatcheries, feed mills, processing
    plants and distribution systems.  They own the birds which are placed
    on farms,  supply feed and medication and then process  the birds.  The
    farmer,  or grower,  supplies land, buildings, equipment, and  labor.
    For these facilities and/or functions he receives a stipulated rate per
    pound of broilers produced.
    
    The individual grower is dependent upon a contractor integrator for
    survival.   Management decisions are  made by the contrai tor with tne
    grower making only the  basic decision to grow or not grow out broilers.
    
    Number and Size of Production Units
    
    In 1969 the Agricultural Census  reported 23,704 growers producing
    broilers.   This represented a decrease in grower numbers of  6,050
    since 1964 (Table VII-1).  The decrease in  grower numbers was a
    function of smaller growers leaving broiler production.  In the five
    year interva 1 between 1964 and 1969, 10,592 growers producing less than
    60,000 birds each discontinued production.
    
    Production has become concentrated in units of 60,000  or  more birds.
    The number of units  producing 60,000 or more birds annually  increased
    from 10, 282 in 1964  to 14, 824 in 1969-  These larger producers in
    1969 produced 80 percent of all birds  compared to 66 percent in 1964.
                                    VII-1
    

    -------
                                    Figure  VII-1
               FUNCTIONS OF  A TYPICAL INTEGRATED BROILER FIRM
    
                                     Reody-To-Cook
                                        Broilers
                                       Processing
                                         Plant
                                            Live Broilers
              Broiler Feed and
                Flock Service
      Broiler Growout:
    (1) Contract Growers
    (2) Company Farms
    Broiler Chicks
                                       (1) Contract
                                       (2) Company
    Source:   U. S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service,
              The Chicken Broiler Industry:  Structure,  Practices,  and Costs,
              Marketing Research Report No.
                                      VII-2
                 930, May, 1971.
    

    -------
                Table  Vll-i.Number of farms selling broilers and number  sold, 1964 and  1969, U. S.
                                                 forty-eight states.
    19691/ 1964ji/
    Broilers sold
    2,000-3.999
    4,000-7, 999
    8.000-15.999
    16, 000-29,999
    30,000-59, 999
    60,000-99,999
    100, 000 or more
    
    No
    Farms
    
    
    1 ,
    2,
    8.
    7,
    7,
    28,
    188
    555
    63 ^
    923
    576
    194
    630
    704
    Percent
    Percent Broilers
    Farms Sold
    0.
    I.
    5.
    10.
    29.
    25.
    26.
    100.
    7
    9
    7 1
    2 3
    9 16
    1 22
    5 5>)
    0 100
    No.
    Farms
    1,
    1,
    4,
    6,
    10,
    5,
    4,
    34,
    003
    818
    336
    862
    453
    886
    396
    754
    Pe.rcent
    Farms
    2.
    5.
    12.
    19-
    30.
    16.
    12.
    100.
    9
    2
    5
    7
    2
    9
    6
    0
    Percent
    Broilers
    Sold
    -
    -
    3
    8
    23
    23
    43
    100
    _  All farms with sales of $2500 or more.  Sales  of broilers and other meat type chickens less than
       three months old.  1969 U.S. Census of Agriculture.
    
    _  All farms.  Number  of broilers and other meat type chickens  sold.  1964 Census of Agriculture.
    

    -------
                                  Percent Growers    Percent Broilers Grown
    Growers producing
    Less than 60, 000 birds
    60,000 - 99,999
    100, 000 or more
    1964
    70
    17
    13
    1969
    48
    25
    27
    1964
    34
    23
    43
    1969
    20
    22
    58
    Of the larger growers there were 7, 630 in 1969, who produced more than
    100, 000 birds each per year.  These growers in total,  grew 58 per-
    cent of all broilers grow.n.   The' number of growers in  this size category
    increased by seventy-three percent.  Production is being increasingly
    concentrated with larger growers and will probably increase in the future.
    Fewer and larger growers can significantly affect an integrator's cost
    by reducing costs associated with feed delivery,  bird pickup, and super-
    visory field management.
    
    Volume of Marketings
    
    Broiler production has grown rapidly since its infancy  in the mid-thirties,
    Production equalled 43 million birds in 1935,  increasing to  1, 092 million
    by 1955 and in  1972,  3, 075 million  birds.  During the past  seven years,
    the number  of commercial broilers produced has increased by  thirty-
    two percent.  In  1972,  over  three billion broilers were produced repre-
    senting increases in production of over 650 million birds  since 1965.
                                     Million Birds            Percent change
    Year                              Produced                1965 to 1972
    
    1965                                2,334
    1966                                2,571                       10
    1967                                2,592                       11
    1968                                2,620                       12
    1969                                2,789                       20
    1970                                2,987                       28
    1971                                2,945                       26
    1972                                3,075                       32
    
    Gross receipts from broilers equalled $1.492 million in 1971,  representing
    2.8 percent of gross farm income. J_' In several states, broiler production
    comprises a significant portion of gross farm income.  In Delaware, one-
    half of all farm income is derived from broilers.  Other states in which
    —  Gross receipts from live birds.  It does not represent the receipts received
       by an individual grower producing birds on contract.
                                     VII-4
    

    -------
    broiler production represents significant  portions of farm  income are
    Maryland (26. 1 percent), Alabama (21. 1 percent), Maine (19.6 percent),
    Arkansas (18.8 percent), and Georgia (15.9 percent).
    
    Age of Production Facilities
    
    There is limited information available pertaining to the age of grow out
    facilities.   A study of broiler growers in  Louisiana in 1966 reported
    the average age of broiler houses to be 6.7 years.—'
    
    The age of  facilities 'can be assumed to be highly correlated with growth
    in production.   States such as Arkansas,  Virginia, Alabama,  Mississippi,
    North Carolina,  and Texas have l-.ad increases in production,  since 1965,
    of twenty-five  percent or more.  These increases combined with an
    exodus  of smaller producers necessitates the construction of new housing.
    Therefore,  we can assume that housing in these states would be newer
    than in those states where production has  remained relatively stable.
    
    Average age of housing in the growth states is estimated to be 10
    years of age.  Ages of housing  in other areas is estimated to be
    15 years.
     Location of Major Production Segments
    
     Major production areas are located in the northwestern corner of Arkansas;
     northern Georgia and Alabama; Central  Mississippi;  east Texas, southern
     Maine; the Delmarva Peninsula of Maryland, Delaware and Virginia;
     central  North Carolina and California.   These areas  account for a majority
     of all production with other areas having limited output.
    
     The ten leading broiler  producing states produce eighty-four percent of
     all "broilers  grown in the United States.   The three leading  states of
     Arkansas, Georgia and  Alaba-ma  alone produce forty-five percent of all
     broilers.  Of the ten leading states, all  but Maine, Delaware and Maryland
     are located in the South and/or South Central area.
    J_/ "Costs and Returns in Producing and Marketing Broilers Under Contract
        in Louisiana,"  E.P.  Roy andF.R. Baker,  Louisiana State University,
        Agr.  Exp. Station,  D.A.E. Re search Report No. 380.
                                        VII-5
    

    -------
                                           Percent of
             State                          U.S. Prod.
             Arkansas                         17.3
             Georgia                          14.4
             Alabama                         13.0
             North Carolina                    9. 8
             Mississippi                       8. 3
             Texas                             5.8
             Maryland         •                 5.8
             Delaware                          4. 3
             Virginia                           2. 5
             Maine                             2.3
                                              83.5
    
    Growth in the industry since 1965 has not been spread evenly in major
    producing areas.  States  in which production has increased more rapidly
    than the national average of thirty-two percent are Arkansas,  Virginia,
    Alabama and Mississippi.  Many of the traditional producing states
    such as Georgia and Maine have had only modest increases in production.
    
                                        Change in Production
             State                          1965 to 1972
    
             Arkansas                          67%
             Virginia                           61
             Alabama                          53
             Mississippi                        53
             North Carolina                    29
             Texas                             26
             Maryland                          22
             Delaware                          21
             Georgia                           10
             Maine                               4
    
    Level of Technology and Efficiency
    
    Broiler production has  been characterized by rapid adoption of increasing
    efficiency.  Improved housing,  automation in  feeding and watering, pre-
    ventative disease management,  improved rations,  and faster growing
    birds have all resulted in reducing costs of production.  In a  recent
    report by the  U.S.D.A.  gains in broiler production were characterized
    by the  following quotation:
                                      VII-6
    

    -------
          "The greater-than-50-percent reduction in price and cost from 1949
           to 1969 was possible because of substantial increases in production
           efficiency.  Primary breeders have improved broiler strains
           sufficiently to reduce the time needed to produce a 3. 5-pound
           live bird from 12-14 weeks 20 years ago to 8-9 weeks now.
           Poultry  nutritionists have developed improved  feed formulations
           which have  helped reduce the amount of feed needed to produce
           1 pound  of live broiler from 4 pounds in 1940 to 2. 2 pounds today.
           Mortality rates of 10 to 20 percent were common 20 years ago,
           while a rate of more than 6 percent is  considered high today.
           Man-hours  per 1,000 broilers prod-iced declined from 250 in 1940
           to 15 in  1969  as a result of  increased mechanization,  more efficient
           farm layouts, and larger flock sizes.  Recent improvements in
           modern  poultry housing have  stressed  ;omplete environmental
           control;  that is,  control of light, temperature, humiditv, and air
           movement.  Although further gains in efficiency are possible,  it
           is difficult to see how they can be 01 the magnitude of those in  the
           past 20 years. "_
    Tncrcaseci efficiencies can be accomplished in broiie-r production wuh
    emphasis today being placed on housing,  handling and feeding >>i birds.
    At present, most broilers are grown in confine.-, housing with housing
    having 20, 000 to r.O, 000 square foot of space.  Birds are tree to roam
    throughout this  space,  manure is deposited on liner which may or may
    not be removed after each batch, and birds ure • ubiected to changes in
    temperature.
    
    Changes in production practices which  could lead to increased efficiency
    were discussed by Dr. Hal Yacowitz in a recent odilion of Feedstuffs
    Magazine..'.:'  Dr..  Yacowitz suggestions were:
    
            -Stabilise   the environmental  temperature  m house? io about
             70 degrees t'ahrenheit.   Feed conversion is reduced by either
             higher or lower temperatures.
            -Darker houses to  reduce
            -Use partitions within a house fo confine b^rds to smaller groups.
             Smaller groups have less activity due to fewer disruptions and
             activity in  establishing pecking orders.
    _!' "The Chicken Broiler Industry, Structure,  Practices and Costs",
        U..S.D.A.,  E.R.S., Marketing Research  Report No.  930, May,  1971.
    _' "Reducing Costs in Broiler Production,"  Dr. Hal Yacowitz, Dir.  of
        Research and Nutrition Services, The Amburgo Co. ,  Inc. , Philadelphia,
        Pa., Feedstuffs, February 12, 1973.
    
                                       VII-7
    

    -------
            -Use meal feeding instead of continuous feeding.  Feed efficiency
             increases if birds are fed meals instead of being allowed to
             continuously nibble.
    
    Level of Integration
    
    The broiler industry is highly integrated with 95 percent or more  of all
    broilers produced under contract or by integrated firms.  In  this system
    broilers are produced and marketed under contract between the grower
    (farmer) and contractor (integrator) where each bears  a  specified part
    of the costs and risks  in production.  Generally, growers provide
    housing, equipment, litter,  power, and labor.  The contractor furnishes
    chicks,  feed,  medicines and field supervision.
    
    In this contractional arrangement, title to broilers  remains with the
    contractor.  The  grower in essence  rents a fixed facility and labor to
    the contractor and receives a  fee based on pounds of birds  produced.
    The fee or payment received varies  from one production area to another
    depending upon the type of contract.
    
    Some representative contracts are as follows:
    
    Feed conversion - payment in this contract is based on feed conversion
    rate.  The grower receives a  payment of 1 to 2 1/2 cents per pound
    depending on his feed  conversion rate per flock.
    
    Prime Cost - minimum guarantee per thousand birds started.  A  growers
    payment is based on his average  production costs relative  to the average
    production costs of all growers with the contractor during  the two weeks
    prior to settlement.  There is a minimum guarantee per thousand birds
    started and all profits above the guarantee are divided between the
    contractor and growers.
    
    Cost of Production grouping - Growers are paid from  1 1/2 to 2 1/4 cents
    per pound of broilers  raised.  Payments are determined by comparing
    each grower's cost of production to that of the most  efficient grower.
    
    Feed conversion-body weight - Growers receive a base payment of 1 1/2
    cents per pound.  A bonus is paid to growers based on feed conversion and
    average broiler weight.
    
    Prime production costs -  Growers receive 2 cents per pound plus or minus
    the full amount of the  difference between his cost of production and the
    average cost  of all growers, depending on whether the cost of production
    is above or below the  average of all growers.  Minimum payment is guaranteed
    not to be less; than 1.5 cents per pound.
    
                                      VII-8
    

    -------
    Level of Diversification
    
    With the exception of the California area broiler production is concentrated
    in areas in which growers have limited farming alternatives.  The  topogra-
    phy  of the  land and  soil fertility are not conducive for intensive crop and/or
    livestock production.  These areas are deficit in grain production and
    require imports of  feed grains for survival of the broiler industry.
    
    In most of the major  producing areas, broiler production is  considered as
    a part time occupation, particularly for growers with housing capacity
    of 40,000 or less birds.  Many of these.- bmaller producers grow broilers
    to supplement off farm income and to more fully utilize family labor.
    
    Limited research on  grower characteristics indicates that beef brood
    cows is the next best alternate e for broiler growers.  Most growers do
    have some  acreage which can best- b<.  used for grazing cattle.
    
    Once committed to  broiler production bv building housing growers iiave
    few  alternatives.  With modifications, nuusing facilities couid DC used
    for other poultry such as layers  or brooding turkey pouits,  but have
    limited possibilities for use in producing livestock.
             B.  Number of Plants and Employment by Segments
    
    In 1969, the Agricultural Census reported 28, 704 farm? producing broilers.
    These producers were further classified by the number of broilers  sold.
    The number of farms for each size classification are as follows:
    
             Broilers Sold                       Number Farms
             2,000-3,999                               185
             4,000-7,999                               555
             8,000-15,993                            1,638
            16, 000-29, 99q                            2,923
            30,000-59,999                            8,576
            60,000-99, 999                            7, 194
           100, 000  or more                          7, 630
                                                     28,704
    
    Limited data is available on the number of people employed on these
    farm units.  Noles in a study of Georgia broiler growers reported that
    eighty percent of the labor used on broiler farms consisted of family labor.-I'
    -I' "Broiler Production in Georgia:  Growers Costs and Returns, "  R.K. Noles,
       M.Y.  Dendy,  University of Georgia,  Research Report No.  34,  Dec. 1968.
    
                                       VII-9
    

    -------
    While some farms hired full-time  caretakers, most farms limited hired
    labor for the cleaning operation.
    
    The number of people employed in broiler production was estimated
    using the following assumptions:  (1) a grower and his family can handle
    a flock of 60,000 birds; and (2) each incremental addition of 60,000
    birds requires an additional full-time hired hand.  Using these assump-
    tions, total labor employed on broiler production units approximates
    39,930 persons excluding family labor.
    
                                                    Employees         Total
    Size of Flock              Number Farms        Per Unit        Employment
    
         <59,999                 13,880                1                13,880
     60,000-99,999              7,194               1.5               10,790
    100,000  or more              7,630               2.0               15,260
                                 28,704                                39,930
              C.  Relationships of Segments to Total Industry
    
    Number of Production Units
    
    Of the 28, 704 broiler production units,  eighty-four percent are located
    in ten states.  The largest number of production units are located in the
    South and South Central states and include Georgia, Arkansas, Alabama,
    North Carolina,  Mississippi,  Texas, Maryland, Delaware,  Virginia
    and Maine.
    
                                    Number Production     Number Birds
    State                              Units - 1969  	     Produced - 1972
                                                             --1,000--
    Georgia                                5,351              442,937
    Arkansas                               4,259              532,135
    Alabama                               4,419              399,274
    North Carolina                         3,187              301,772
    Texas                                  1,727              178,511
    Maryland                               1,444              177,247
    Mississippi                             1,431              256,264
    Delaware                               1,065              131,873
    Virginia                                 746                77,238
    Maine                                    551                71,344
       Total                               24,180            2,568,595
    
     Production
     Broiler production by states is highly correlated with the number of pro-
     duction units (growers).  The ten leading broiler states have  84 percent  of
     all production units and account for the  same percentage of birds raised
     (Fig ire VTI-2).
                                      VII-!0
    

    -------
    Figure vii-z,   BROILERS AND OTHER MEAT-TYPE CHICKENS SOLD, NUMBER 1S69
    *'.'•.'•'
                                                                                   I DOT = 500,000 IIROS
    
                                                                                   41 STATE TOTH • 2.42M41.02I
            Source;  Poultry and Egg Situation,  Economic Research Service, U.S.  Department of
                     Agriculture, November 1972.
    

    -------
    There is considerable variation, by states, in the percentage of broilers
    raised by larger growers.  In Maine, Maryland, Delaware,  Virginia, and
    Texas,  over 60 percent of all broilers are grown by producers  growing
    more than 100,000 birds annually (TabLe VII-2).  In comparison,  less than
    half the birds in Mississippi,  Georgia,  and Alabama are produced by
    these larger growers.
    
    Employment
    
    The number of people employed in broiler production  is assumed to
    approximate the number of production units.  The limited hired labor
    employed is used primarily to assist in cleaning houses either  after
    each flock is grown or annually.  Cleaning requirements depend upon
    a contractors  management practices.
                                   VII-12
    

    -------
    Table \il-2.  Number of farms with broilers sold by size, ten leading states
    
    Arkansas
    No. farms
    Percent farms
    Percent broilers
    Georgia
    No. farms
    Percent farms
    Percent broilers
    Alabama
    < No. farms
    "-1 Percent farms
    ^ Percent broilers
    North Carolina
    No. farms
    Percent farms
    Percent broilers
    Mississippi
    No. farms
    Percent farms
    Percent broilers
    1- 2- 4-
    1,999 3,999 7,999
    
    10 7 42
    * •:= 1 . 0
    ;',; :;: ;]:
    
    10 13 71
    * * 1.3
    
    
    9 15 66
    * --:- 1 . 5
    =;= * *
    
    17 7 34
    * * 1.1
    * * *
    
    5 515
    * * 1.1
    •f * *
    Number of
    8-
    15,999
    
    146
    3.4
    ;|;
    
    240
    4. 5
    *
    
    184
    4. 1
    
    
    177
    5.6
    ;];
    
    60
    4. 2
    1.7
    Broilers
    16-
    29,999
    
    243
    5. 7
    1. 5
    
    623
    11.6
    3. 7
    
    482
    10 . 9
    
    
    294
    9- 2
    2. 7
    
    46
    3. 3
    4. 2
    Sold
    30-
    59,999
    
    1 ,232
    28. 9
    15. 1
    
    1,855
    34. 7
    21. 6
    
    1,780
    40. 4
    23. 2
    
    940
    29- 5
    15. 9
    
    260
    18. 1
    25. 5
    60-
    99,999
    
    1,301
    30. 6
    26. 1
    
    1,461
    27. 3
    29- 1
    
    1, 163
    26. 3
    26. 2
    
    863
    27. 1
    26. 1
    
    320
    22.4
    23. 6
    100 ,000
    
    1 ,278
    30. 0
    56. 8
    
    1,078
    20. 2
    44. 8
    
    720
    16. 3
    46. 6
    
    855
    26. 8
    54. 4
    
    720
    50. 3
    44. 5
    Total
    
    4,259
    100
    100
    
    5, 351
    100
    100
    
    4,419
    100
    100
    
    3, 187
    100
    100
    
    1,431
    100
    100
    

    -------
             II.  BROILER INDUSTRY - FINANCIAL PROFILE
    The focal point of this financia I analysis is the farmer who grows broilers
    on a contract for a contractor (integrator).   Under the provisions of the
    contract, growers (farmers) provide housing,  feeding, water,  utilities
    and labor.  He does not  take title to birds, buys  no  feed and accepts
    supervision from  a field man employed by contractors-  In simplest
    terms,  the grower rents production facilities to  a contractor.  In turn
    growers receive a rental payment based upon the number of pounds
    of birds grown.
                          A.   Plants by Segment
    
    The financial profile of two contract growers are used in this analysis.
    One grower is located in Maine and the other in Georgia.  Both growers
    •were assumed to have the same capacity houses  and produce the same
    number of birds.  Differences existed in investment costs and annual
    operating expenses.
    
    This methodology was used rather than developing financial profiles  for
    successfully larger growers.  It  is our opinion that financial profiles
    vary more between  regions than by size of operations.  Economies of
    scale in grow out  operations are  not relevant for the existing  structure
    of growers.  Costs are a function of the number  of birds grown with
    a producer growing 20,000 birds at one time having basically the same
    per unit cost of a  grower with a flock of 50 or  100 thousand  birds. (For
    a description of model plant see Table VII-9).
    
    Annual Profit Before Taxes
    The  estimated annual pre-tax net income for growers in Georgia and Maine,
    producing about 1 87, 000 broilers annually was $2,077 and $3,189 respec-
    tively (Table VII-3).
    
    The  difference between Georgia and Maine rates of return on investment
    both before and after tax, is  due largely to different levels of investment
    required (which tend to be determined by region) and different contract
    payment levels.  In Georgia the moderately efficient grower ma/ expect
    a return of 2. 2£/lb.  while in Maine the same grower could expect 2. 6£/lb.
    It is significant to note that a  . 1^/lb. increase in contract payments yields
                                      VII-14
    

    -------
       Table VII- 3.  Estimated pre-tax income and rate of return on average
                 invested capital and after-tax return on sales for
                              broiler operations
    Financial Measure Georgia
    Pre-tax net income • 2,077
    Pre-tax ROI* (%) 6.9
    After-tax ROI* (%) 5.4
    After-tax return on sales (%) 11.8
    Maine
    3,189
    8. 6
    6. 7
    15. 3
    '^J Average return on fixed investment calculated by financial statement method-
                                     VII-15
    

    -------
    an increase of $187 which in Georgia represents a  9% increase in pre-
    tax net income, and in Maine a 5. 9% increase.
    
    It is also important to note that contract payments  are also often tied to
    feed conversion ratios which is an indication of the efficiency with which
    a bird converts feed to meat.  Skillful management by growers will  enhance
    the feed  conversion ratio  and thus improve the  return to the  grower.  This
    situation can cause widely differing yields even between similar growers
    in a region.  We believe our estimates however, represent average growers
    in the regions  indicated.
    
    Annual Cash Flow
    
    Estimated annual cash flow  is calculated by adding depreciation charges
    to after tax net income.  The percentage cash flow on average fixed invest-
    ment and the annual cash  flow are  shown in Table VII-4 for selected growers.
    Depreciation rates  for growers is  based on a  useful life of buildings of
    12. 5 years and of equipment of 8 years.  Buildings represent approximately
    60% of total investment and  equipment approximately 40%.  The rates of
    depreciation are based on industry averages.
    
    The majority of the growers apply tneir annual cash flow two fold,  one
    to retire government  insured loans used to acquire facilities and secondly,
    to live on.  The majority of farmer type growers typically do not attempt
    to reinvest depreciation and earnings nor accumulate   it to replace  worn
    out facilities,  bat rather simply apply these funds  to pay for  the day to day
    expenses of living and maintaining a family
    
    In our estimates we are excluding family labor as  an expense since  it is
    difficult to measure.   However, when an attempt to include family labor
    is made, both  Georgia and Maine growers show a negative pre-tax income
    (See Table VII-5).
    
    Market (Salvage)  Value of Assets
    
    The facilities  required to produce broilers is simple in nature, a facility
    to house the  birds with adequate  heating facilities to meet climate conditions
    and feeding equipment that tends to be highly  specialized to the needs  of
    b 'oilers.
    
    The house arid heating equipment  could  presumably be converted into
    alternative uses at a  value of 15%  of original  investment  The feeding
    equipment would  have little or no salvage vetlue since  :t is highly specialized
    equipment.  Alternative uses might include  other livestock operations,
    storage  facilities,  or  some type  of machine shop  It  is also  assumed that
    the  grower could recover his working capital  requirements
                                        Vll-ih
    

    -------
         Table VII- I-  Estimated rash flow for broiler operations
    Financial Measure
    Georgia
    Maine
    Annual Cash Flow
     7,402
    9,172
    Cash Flow on Average
      Fixed Investment { %)
     24. 5
     24. 8
                                       VII-17
    

    -------
       Table VII- 5.      Estimated cash flow for a broiler operation,
                  Georgia and Maine, floor system,  1971
    
    Utilization
    Annual Output (pounds of broilers)
    Sales -
    Fixed Expenses
    Variable Expenses
    Cash Earnings
    Depreciation
    Interest
    P re -Tax Income
    Excluding Family Labor
    Cash Earnings
    Depreciation
    Interest
    P re -Tax Income
    Georgia
    100%
    627,000
    $ 13,794
    629
    7, 140
    $ 6,025
    5,781
    1,767
    - 1,523
    
    $ 9,625
    5,781
    1,767
    2,077
    Maine
    100%
    627,000
    $ 16,302
    2, 110
    5,760
    $ 8,432
    6,684
    2, 159
    -411
    
    $ 12,032
    6,684
    2, 159
    3, 189
    —' Assumes average prices paid to contract growers of:
       2.2 cents/lb in Georgia
       2.6 cents/lb in Maine
                                     VII-18
    

    -------
    Capital Structure
    
    It may be assumed that entry into the broiler industry is relatively easy,
    in that only moderate capital is required to build the facilities required.
    (See Table VII-6).  The necessary capital is readily available to qualified
    farmers through various government insured loans on reasonable terms
    to the farmer.
    
    Only a minimum of working capital is  required which would be provided
    by the farmer,  representing-his only personal outlay to establish the
    business.
    
    Tie total capital required is a  direct function of the desired level of
    output with virtually  no economies of scale.
    
    Cost Structure
    
    Model broiler grower data and budgets were prepared to estimate the cost
    structure of  representative operations.
    
    Fixed expenses were defined as those  which do not  vary in relation to number
    of broilers started-   These include:  (See Table VII-7)
    
                  • Depreciation
                  • Insurance and Taxes
                  - Interest on investment
    
    Variable expenses ass those expenses that are a function of the number of
    birds started.  These include:  (See  Table VII-7).
    
                  • Power (Heat, electricity)
                  - Litter
                  • Repairs and Maintenance
                  • Clean out
                  • Miscellaneous
    
    Fixed <. osts make up approximately  59- 3% of sales  in Georgia and 67. 2%
    of sales  in Maine ,  while  variable costs represent  25. 7% in Georgia  and
    13.  2% in Maine- Such a cost structure is  typical for the contract  broiler
    industry since the grower does not incur  costs associated with purchase
    of chicks or feed. (See Table  VII-8).
                                       VII-19
    

    -------
      Table VII-  6.    Estimated replacement value and working capital
                     requirements for broiler operation
    Capital component                         Georgia            Maine
    
    Replacement value of facilities
    and equipment                             57,480              71,100
    
    Net working capital   .       '                 1,428                1,440
    
    Replacement value of total assets           58,908              72,540
                                     VII-20
    

    -------
      Table VII-7.   Total investment and annual costs of growing broilers,
          thirty thousand square foot houses in Georgia and Maine, 1971
                                                Georgia
                          Maine
    Investment Costs
       Building
       Heating System
       Feeding Equipment
       Total Investment
    $31,200
      5,630
     20,650
    $57,480
    $42,000
     10,300
     18, 800
    $71,100
    Annual Fix?d Costs
    Deprec lation
    Puildlng (8%)
    Heating System (12.5%)
    Feeders (12.5%)
    Insurance and Taxes
    Interest
    Total Fixed Costs
    Annual Variable Costs
    Electricity
    Heat
    Litter
    Repairs and Maintenance
    Clean Out
    Miscellaneous
    Labor
    Total Variable Costs
    Total Costs
    Total Costs excluding labor
    
    
    2,496
    704
    2, 581
    627
    1,938
    $8,346
    
    370
    1,530
    890
    400
    150
    200
    3,600
    $ 7, 140
    $13,548
    $ 9,948
    
    
    2,814
    1,370
    2, 500
    2,110
    2,305
    $9,099
    
    690
    x —
    X I/
    510
    450
    510
    3,600
    $ 5,760
    $14,554
    $10,954
    Source;  Data were derived from the following secondary sources and updated by
             contact with University and industry personnel.
    
             "Estimated Cash Flows and Profitability of Maine Broiler Farms,"
             K. E. Wing and W.C.  Geiss, Jr., Life Sciences and Agriculture
             Experiment Station, University of Maine at Orono,  Bulletin 694,
             Dec. , 1971.
             "Broiler Production in Georgia:  Grower's Costs and Returns," R. K-
             Noles and M. Y.  Dendy, College of Agriculture Experiment Station,
             University of Georgia, Research Report 34,  Dec. ,  1968,
             _' Heat and litter are provided by contractors.
                                        VII-21
    

    -------
           Table VII-8.  Estimated costs for broiler operations
                                      Georgia	            Ma ine
       Item	($)    Percent	($)   Percent
    
    
    
    
    
    Sales!/                       13,794                  16,302
    
    
    
    
    
    Raw Materials                  -0-                     -0-
    
    
    
    
    
    Direct Operating Cos.ts     '    3,540    25. 7           2,160    13.2
    
    
    
    
    
    Indirect Operating Costs          629     4.6           2,110    12.9
    
    
    
    
    
    Depreciation                   5,781    41.9           6,684    41.0
    
    
    
    
    
    Interest                        1,767    12 8           2,159    13.3
    
    
    
    
    
    Total before-tax cost          11,717    85.0          13,113    80.4
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
    !/ See Table VII-7
                                     VII-22
    

    -------
    Labor is not a variable cost since it is normally provided by owners
    and therefore the cost of owner provided labor is the residual after
    all other costs are deducted.
                   B.   Ability to Finance New Investment
    
    Since the broiler grower operation requires relatively little capital
    investment as compared to other industries in the United States,
    the broiler industry tends to be comprised primarily of single
    proprietorship farmer units.
    
    The farmer typically finds several available sources for capital
    financing. These are primarily government insured load programs
    such as Production Credit Association and Farmers Home Adminis-
    tration.   In addition to these,  financing is available from local banks
    via mortages on personal farm property as well as through the con-
    tractors themselves.
    
    It is assumed that the typical farmer operated broiler operation would
    have little difficulty in acquiring additional financing for new investment.
                                     VII-23
    

    -------
            Table VII- 9-    Volume of birds produced and prices received
                         by growers, Georgia and Maine, 1971
              House capacity
              Birds started
              Number lot
              Broilers started per year
              Mortality rate
              Broilers delivered to
                 processing  plant
              Gross weight delivered to
                 processing  plant, Ibs.
              Net weight delivered-
                 Gross weight less
                 condemnations
    
              Average prices paid to contract
                 broiler growers  for marketable
                 broilers
    
                       Georgia
                       Maine
    30, 000 sq. foot
    37, 500 each lot
    five
    187,500
    2. 5 percent
    
    182,813
    
    639,845 Ibs.
    
    
    627,048 Ibs.
    2.2 cents/lb
    2.6 c e nt s / Ib
    Source: A Comparison of Returns to Poultry Growers,  ERS, USDA,
            Marketing Research Report, No.  814,  February,  1968.
    
            The Delmarva Poultry Industry in Interregional Competition,
            I.E. Via  andJ.S. Crothers,  Agricultural ExperLnent
            Station,  University of Maryland,  M. P.  750, March 1970.
                                      VII-24
    

    -------
                   PART VIII:  THE TURKEY INDUSTRY
    
    
                     I.   TURKEY INDUSTRY SEGMENTS
    
    
                          A.  Types of Firms
    The turkey industry of today.is a highly concentrated industry with birds
    being produced by relatively few growers within limited geographic areas.
    Turkey production today bears little resemblance to the small farm  flock which
    dominated production systems of several decades ago.
    
    Number ond Size of Production Units
    
    The  1969  Census of Agriculture reported 5, 424 farms  selling turkeys
    (Table VIII-1). These farms averaged selling about 20, 000 birds each.
    
    One-third of all turkey  producers sell less than 2, 000  birds annually.
    These 1,815 producers sold less than one-half  of one percent of all turkeys.
    in 1969.
    
    Most significant are those farms selling 8, 000  or more birds annually.
    There were only 2,617  of these farms in 1969,  but  they sold 95  percent of
    all turkeys.  The average  number of turkeys sold per  farm equalled
    38,583.
    
    Farms in 1969 Selling               Percent Farms        Percent  Turkeys
    
    Less  than 8, 000 birds                     52                      5
    More than 8, 000 birds                    48                     95
    
    Of the larger  growers there were 140 farms in 1969 that sold an average
    of 200, 000 birds each.   These farms produced 26. 4 percent of all turkeys.
    
    Volume of Marketings
    
    The number of turkeys raised has increased during the past seven years
    with production equalling 128, 808, 000  birds in 1972.   This was a produc-
    tion record and represented a twenty percent increase in birds  raised
    since  1965.
                                      VIII-1
    

    -------
    Table VIII-1.   Number of farms with turkeys by size, and percent
                    of turkeys sold, 1964 and 1969
    Size
    1 - 1,999
    2,000 - 3,999
    4,000 - 7,999
    8,000 - 15,999
    16,000 - 29,999
    30,000 - 59,999
    60,000 - 99,999
    100, 000 or more
    Size
    Under 5, 000
    Over 5,000
    
    Number
    Farms
    1,815
    327
    665
    911
    754
    595
    217
    140
    5,424
    
    Number
    Farms
    37,289
    4,331
    41,820
    1969 I/
    Percent
    of Farms
    33. 5
    6.0
    12. 3
    16. 8
    13. 8
    11.0
    4.0
    2.6
    100. 0
    1964£/
    Percent
    of Farms
    89. 1
    10. 9
    100. 0
    
    Percent of
    Turkeys Raised
    0. 4
    1. 0
    4. 0
    11.0
    16. 1
    22. 9
    18. 2
    26. 4
    100. 0
    
    Percent of
    Turkeys Raised
    5. 4
    94. 6
    100. 0
           —  1969 U.S.  Census of Agriculture, Farms with Gross Incomes of
              $2 , 500 or more.
            2/
           —'  1964 U. S. Census of A griculture, All Farms.
                                  VIII-2
    

    -------
            Year                             Turkeys Raised - U.S.
                                                 --1,000 birds--
            1965                                     105,914
    
            1970                                     116,401
            1971                                     120, 121
            1972                                     128,808
    Of the total turkeys raised,  113.8 million were heavy turkeys and 15.0
    million were light birds.  Total pounds of turkeys produced equalled
    2, 424 million in 1972.  Value based on a 22 cent  per  pound farm price
    was $537,249,000.
    
    Age of Production Facilities
    
    There are no known statistics  on  the age of facilities  used by turkey
    growers.  Therefore, age of facilities was estimated by analyzing
    growth in production and date on the average life expectancy of facilities.
    
    Housing  used in turkey grow-out operations consist of a house to brood
    poults in and in some areas, such as Minnesota and Virginia, pole sheds
    for semi-confining birds.
    
    The production systems used for  growing turkeys involves placing day-
    old poults in brooding houses.   At about eight weeks of age,  poults are
    moved to open  range with limited  shelter or placed in semi-confinement
    The latter practices  consists of providing about two square feet of  housing
    for  poults and also range.
    
    The average age of brooder and pole sheds used for semi-confinement is
    estimated to be ten years, one-half the average life expectancy.
    
    Location of Major Production Segments
    
    Turkey production is concentrated in ten major producing  states with
    increased concentration occurring during the past seven years.   These
    ten states produced 77 percent of  all birds  in 1972 compared to  71 percent
    in 1965 (Figure VIII-1).
    
    Minnesota is the  leading state producing 16.2 percent of all turkeys  in
    1972.  California ranks second and is  followed by North Carolina and
    Missouri.  These four states alone produced 60.6 million birds  in 1972,
    representing 47 percent  of U.S. production.
                                    VIII-3
    

    -------
             Figure vm-1.   TURKEYS SOLD, 1969"
                                                                             48 STATE TOTAL - 103,454.667
    
                                                                             1 DCT = 50,000 BIROS
                                             FARMS WITH SALES OF $2,500 AND OVER
                                             SOURCE • CENSUS DATA
    Source:  Poultry and Egg Situation, Economic Research Service, U.S. Department
              of Agriculture , November 1972.
    

    -------
                                             Percent of U. S.
           Ten leading states                   Production
    
           Minnesota                           16.2
           California                           13.7
           North Carolina                        9. 3
           Missouri                              7. 8
           Arkansas                             6.3
           Texas                                 6. 1
           Iowa                                  5. 1
           Indiana             ,                  4. 7
           Virginia    '                          4. 3
           Ohio                                  3.2
                                                77.7
    
    Significant shifts in turkey production have occurred since 1965.   The
    Carolina's,  Arkansas, Colorado,  Pennsylvania, Indiana and Texas have
    experienced increases in production of 48 percent or more since 1965.
    The growth  rate in the Carolina's between 1965 and 1972 exceeded 150
    percent with North Carolina now being the third largest producing state.
    
    Traditional turkey producing states such as Iowa,  'Wisconsin, Virginia
    and West Virginia have all experienced decreases in production.   The
    number of birds raised in these states decreased by 3, 723, 000 million
    since  1965,  representing an 18 percent decline.
    
    The top twenty produc-ne states ranked in order of percent change
    in production are as follows:
                                      Percent change      Rank in
    State                                1965 - 1972          1972
    
    South Carolina                         169              15
    North Carolina                         156               3
    Arkansas                               70               5
    Colorado                                70              13
    Pennsylvania                            67              14
    Indiana                                 51               8
    Texas                                  48               6
    Utah                                    36              12
    Georgia                                 35              17
    Minnesota                               34               1
    Missouri                                32               4
    Oklahoma                               24              18
    Oregon                                 20              16
    Ohio                                    16              10
    California                               13               2
    North Dakota                             6              20
    Virginia                                -3               9
    Iowa                                   -20               7
    Wisconsin                             -26              11
    West  Virginia                          -30              19
    
                                     VIII-5
    

    -------
    Level of Technology and Efficiency
    
    The technology used in growing turkeys has not changed greatly during
    the past  decade.  Day old poults are started in brooder houses,  which
    provide heat if needed and shelter.   These poults are started on floors
    with litter used to collect excretions.
    
    At about eight weeks  of age poults are either placed on open range or
    placed in semi-confined or totally confined systems.  Industry personnel
    estimate that 70 percent are grown on open range, Z5 percent in semi-
    confinement and 5 percent in totally confined systems.  The type of
    system used will vary by geographic location.   In Minnesota,  semi and
    total confinment   systems  represent the principal management  system.
    In California most birds are grown in  sem i-confinem ent.   In Missouri,
    and many areas of the South and Southwest, the majority of birds are
    grown on range.
    
    The use  of semi-confinement and fully confined production units are
    increasing.  Semi-confinement systems  involve construction of housing
    providing about two square foot of space per birds.  Houses provide
    shelter at night and during  inclimate weather.   At other times poults are
    free to roam on open range.  Fully confinement systems require about
    four square foot of space with birds being  confined from  the time of hatching
    to being  processed.
    
    Both types of confinement systems  require additional investment relative
    to open range systems.  As production of poults becomes less  seasonal,
    industry personnel anticipate increased use of semi  and full  confinement.
    houses.
    
    Efficiency in growing turkey poults is  poor relative to broilers.  It is the
    opinion of some industry personnel that efficiency in turkey production is
    ten years behind the  level achieved in broiler production.
    
     Efficiency standards used in  turkey production include feed conversion
     rates, percent liveability  and the percent of birds grading Grade A.  In
     turkey production, the efficiency levels of individual producers will vary
     greatly about industry norms.  In broiler production, efficiency levels of
     individual growers are generally clustered near industry averages .
                                    VIII-6
    

    -------
    Efficiency standards used in turkey production and normal variation
    occurring  are as follows:
    
           Feed Conversion                  Feed/pound of Gain
                                            Hens        Toms
           Norm                       3.00-3.05   3. 15-3.25
           Excellent                    2.80-2.90       3.05
           Poor                            3.40         3.60
    
           j-iive ability
    
           Norm                                90 percent
           Excellent                             ^5 percent
           Poor                                 70 percent
    
           Grades - Percent Grading Grade A
    Norm
    Excellent
    Poor
    Hens
    82-33%
    85%
    30%
    Toms
    67-70%
    75%
    5%
    Significant variation occurs in liveability clu-j to outbreaks  of cholera,
    blue comb disease and leg problems.  The latter problem is most evident
    in tom's because of heavier body weight.
    
    Variation in Grades occur due to damage Lo  exterior portions of a turkeys
    body.  Scratches, bruises and infested sores from chiggers require
    " cut-outs"  and therefore a lower grade  bird.
    
    Efforts to overcome these factors include toe clipping to prevent scratching,
    better disease prevention and better range managemtnt.  At present, little
    progress is being made and considerable improvement is required before
    optimum  efficiency levels are achieved.
    
    Level of Integration
    
    An estimated 90  percent or more of all turkeys .it  present are grown on some
    type of contractional arrangement between a grower and an integrator (contractor).
    Contracts vary greatly from specific payments to growers on production contracts
    to agreements  by integrators to process and market a grower's birds.  Some
    typical contractional arrangements were outlined by Rhodes in  discussions
    of turkey production in Missouri._j_/
    _  Changes in Turkey Contracting,  1967-68, Agricultural Experiment Station,
       University of Missouri at Columbia, Station Bulletin 886, March, 1970.
                                     VIII-7
    

    -------
           I.   Production Payment Contract
              "This type of contract shares production risks between grower
           and contractor (feed company or processor or both),  but the con-
           tractor takes all of the market price  risk for the birds contracted
           because the contractor owns  the birds."
    The production payment is a price wage for output accomplished.   The
    contractor pays the  producer so much per pound for turkeys  marketed.
    This payment may include incentives for other aspects of performance
    such as mortality and feed efficiency.  In another form  of this type
    contract,  the size of the per'pound payment is related to the  costs of
    production for a flock as compared to average costs of all comparable
    flocks owned by that contractor.
    
           II.   Floor Price Contract
    The grower owns  the birds, takes all of the production risks and shares
    the price  risks with the contractor.   In turn,  the contractor  guarantees
    to purchase the birds at either a price which  is no lower than a  fixed
    minimum (floor) or  at a schedule of prices related to market prices.
    In the usual case, the grower  trades part of  his potential  profit  if market
    prices are high for a guaranteed floor price  if they are  low.
    
          III.   Financing Contract
    The grower owns  the birds and takes all production and price risks.  How-
    ever, in return for  contractor financing of turkey production, the grower
    agrees to buy the  contractor's feed and/or to sell the finished birds to the
    contractor.
    
          IV.  Marketing Contract
              "A marketing agreement constitutes an agreement of a processor
           t-o market  a  grower's birds and to  return to him the net proceeds above
           processing,  storage and other costs.  Such an agreement is equivalent
           to a forward sale at an undetermined price.  It insures a market for
           an otherwise independent grower, and it likewise  schedules processing
           business for the processor.  These purely marketing agreements
           should not be confused with floor price contracts which are often titled
           marketing agreements."
    
           V.  Profit  Share Contract
    There is  great variety of  definitions of pr.fits, risks, and management.
    Generally, the producer supplies  land, equipment and labor  while the
    contractor furnishes the rest.
    
    To grow turkeys a farmer must either have  an arrangement  with  a processor
    to process his birds or do his own processing.  The latter is not  a com.non
    practice.
                                     VIII -8
    

    -------
    Level of Diversification
    
    Turkey production is rapidly becoming a highly specialized farm enterprise.
    As the size of flocks increase more producers are specialising and
    diversification is decreasing.  Farm flocks which  were once u-.ed  to
    complement farm income have become almost nonexistent.
    
    The  opportunity  to diversify into other farming enterprises varies by
    areas of the United States.   In the Ozarks producers have  limited  farming
    alternatives.  In other concentrated producing areas  sued  as the San  Joaquin
    Valley ot California, Central  Minnesota, Texas and the Coastal Plains  of
    N'orth Carolina,  other farming alternatives do exist.  However, with  the
    ixception of California,  most turkeys aie grown in marginal farming areas.
    Climatic  conditions,  typography  of land, and land bases  provide limited
    opportunities tor other farming enterprises.
             JR.  Number oi Plants and Employment bv Segments
    
    The Census  of Agriculture in  1969 reported 5,424 farms Crowing turkey-
    These growers wort  further classified by the number of turkeys sold.   j
    number  of farms for Ui-. se si/.e classifications were as follows:
    
               Turk' vs Sold                       Number Farms
                 -i,ooo-
                    4.0- 7.9                              ^>h5
                    rt.G - 15.9                              91 1
                   :',. o   ?. •, 9                              754
                   ""C. 0 - 5 '->. 9                              595
                   oO.O-'VJ.o                              217
               iOr.O or  more                             i 40
                    rT\;tal                                5, 424
    
    No published n- o rmali on is available on total people  employed in turk<. /
    production rn farms.  Kidman,  L/'.-^n and Carter in a study of Economies
    of Scale in Oai;fornia  I urkey Production,  estimated tne follouir.g labor
    requirements by flo-:k size.
    
               25, OGO birds  = one man
               50, 000 birds  = two men
              100, 000 birds  = three  men
                                      VIII-9
    

    -------
    Using these estimates, the total labor requirements were  estimated
    assuming that:  (1) One entrepreneur would be employed regardless  of
    size. For smaller flocks entrepreneurs would be underemployed; (Z)
    That flocks larger than 25, 000 birds would require hiring  additional
    labor.   This assumes extra family labor was not available.
    
    Using these assumptions, the total number of people employed on
    turkey production units is estimated to be 12, 000 persons.  This includes
    5, 424 farm managers and 6, 576 hired laborers.
              C.  Relationships of Segments to Total Industry
    
    Number  of Production Units
    
    Sixty percent  of all farms with turkeys are located in the ten leading
    turkey producing states (Table VIII-2). Minnesota has 446 turkey growers,
    the largest number of any state.  Missouri ranks second followed in order
    by Texas, Iowa and Indiana.
    
    The size of production units varies significantly among the ten leading
    producing states.   North Carolina has the largest  sales  per unit averaging
    over 66, 000 birds per flock (Table VIII-2). Other  states in which sales
    per farm exceed the  ten state average of 30,511 birds are California,
    Minnesota and Arkansas.
    
    Production
    Turkey production is highly concentrated with ten states accounting for
    77 percent of all birds grown.  Minnesota is the leading state,  producing
    about 21,000,000 birds in 1972.  California ranks second followed in
    order by North Carolina a.id Missouri.
    
    The  concentration of birds by flock sizes varies greatly among the ten
    leading states.  Over half of all turkeys sold in Minnesota, California,
    North Carolina and Texas are produced by farmers  selling 60,  000 or
    more birds annually.   (Table VIII-3).  In the other large producing states,
    sales of 8, 000 -  60, 000 are most common.
    
    Employment
    
    The  number of people employed on farms producing turkeys are a function
    of the number of arid the size of production.  In states such as  Missouri,
    Iowa, Indiana and Ohio,  production units are small and little labor is hired.
                                     VIII-10
    

    -------
      Table VIII-2. Number of farms selling turkeys, number of turkeys sold
              and average  per farm, ten leading states, 1972.
    State
    Minnesota
    California
    North Carolina
    Missouri
    Arkansas
    Texas
    Iowa
    Indiana
    Virginia
    Ohio
    Ten States
    Number ±J
    Farms-1969
    446
    341
    181
    417
    214
    412
    405
    343
    217
    260
    3,236
    Turkeys
    Sold-1972
    -1,000-
    20, 880
    17, 636
    1?., 035
    10, 000
    8, 165
    7, 851
    6, 524
    6, 060
    5,519
    4, 064
    98,734
    Average
    Per Farm
    46, 816
    51,718
    66,492
    23,981
    38, 154
    19,056
    16, 109
    17,668
    25,433
    15,631
    30,511
    _'  1969 Census of Agriculture.
    
    —'  Turkeys, U.S.D.A., S.R.S,  various additions.
                                  VIII- 11
    

    -------
    Table VIII-3.Number of farms raising turkeys and percent of turkeys sold by size,
                                   ten leading states, 1969
    
    Minnesota
    No. Farms
    Percent farms
    Percent Turkeys sold
    California
    I\To. farms
    Percent farms
    Percent turkeys sold
    North Carolina
    No. farms
    Percent farms
    Percent turkeys sold
    Missouri
    No. farms
    percent farms
    Percent turkeys sold
    Arkansas
    No. farms
    Percent farms
    Percent turkeys sold
    1-
    1,999
    
    73
    16.4
    . 2
    
    30
    8. 8
    . 1
    
    12
    6. 6
    . 1
    
    70
    16. 8
    . 4
    
    13
    6. 1
    . 1
    2,000-
    3,999
    
    27
    6
    . 5
    
    12
    3. 5
    . 2
    
    7
    3.9
    1. 1
    
    23
    5. 5
    . 9
    
    8
    3.7
    .4
    4,000-
    4,999
    
    67
    15
    2. 6
    
    24
    7. 1
    1. 0
    
    19
    10. 4
    3. 2
    
    56
    13.4
    4.9
    
    13
    6. 1
    1. 3
    8,000-
    15/999
    
    78
    17. 5
    5-9
    
    53
    15. 5
    4. 1
    
    25
    13.9
    11. 5
    
    112
    26. 8
    18. 9
    
    49
    22. 9
    9. 2
    16,000-
    29,999
    
    61
    13.7
    8.9
    
    58
    17.0
    9-0
    
    46
    25.4
    20. 8
    
    104
    25.0
    31. 8
    
    62
    29.0
    21. 2
    30,000-
    59,999
    
    66
    14. 8
    17. 2
    
    100
    29- 3
    27. 3
    
    45
    24. 9
    12. 2
    
    37
    8.9
    20. 7
    
    53
    24. 8
    34. 9
    60,000-
    99,999
    
    46
    10. 3
    23.0
    
    48
    14. 1
    25. 2
    
    27
    14. 9
    51. 1
    
    10
    2. 4
    11. 0
    
    11
    5. 1
    12. 3
    100,000
    or more
    
    28
    6. 3
    41. 7
    
    16
    4. 7
    33. 1
    
    _
    -
    -
    
    5
    1. 2
    11.4
    
    5
    2. 3
    20. 6
    Total
    
    446
    100%
    100%
    
    341
    100%
    100%
    
    181
    100%
    100%
    
    417
    100%
    100%
    
    214
    100% '
    100%
    

    -------
                                               Table VIII-3. (continued)
    
    Texas
    No. farms
    Percent farms
    Percent turkeys sold
    Iowa
    No. farms
    Percent farms
    Percent turkeys sold
    Indiana
    No. farms
    Percent farms
    Percent turkeys sold
    Virginia
    No. farms
    Percent farms
    Percent turkeys sold
    Ohio
    No. farms
    Percent farms
    Percent turkeys sold
    1-
    1,999
    
    228
    55. 3
    . 3
    
    65
    16. 1
    . 3
    
    37
    10. 8
    . 4
    
    44
    20. 3
    . 3
    
    36
    13. 8
    . 4
    2,000-
    3,999
    
    21
    5. 1
    . 8
    
    48
    11. 9
    2. 6
    
    23
    6. 7
    1. 5
    
    11
    5. 1
    . 8
    
    33
    12. 7
    2. 5
    4,000-
    4,999
    
    41
    10.0
    3. 1
    
    93
    22. 9
    9- 3
    
    84
    24. 5
    10. 4
    
    37
    16. 9
    5. 2
    
    60
    23. 1
    9. 1
    8,000-
    15,999
    
    27
    6. 6
    3. 8
    
    90
    22. 2
    17. 9
    
    114
    33. 2
    27. 7
    
    56
    25. 8
    15. 9
    
    58
    22. 3
    17. 7
    16,000-
    29,999
    
    36
    8. 7
    10. 4
    
    67
    16. 5
    26. 2
    
    52
    15. 2
    23. 3
    
    31
    14. 3
    16. 9
    
    36
    13. 8
    21. 2
    30
    59
    
    
    ,000
    ,999
    
    35
    8. 5
    19
    
    
    7
    23
    
    
    7
    19
    
    
    12
    27
    
    
    11
    29
    . 3
    
    32
    . 9
    . 8
    
    24
    .0
    , 4
    
    26
    .0
    . 1
    
    29
    . 2
    -9
    60,
    99,
    
    1
    3.
    13.
    
    1
    • 2.
    19-
    
    
    2.
    11.
    
    
    2.
    12.
    
    
    2.
    9-
    000-
    99 V
    
    4
    4
    8
    
    0
    5
    9
    
    7
    0
    4
    
    6
    8
    2
    
    5
    0
    6
    100,000
    or more
    
    10
    2.4
    48. 5
    
    _
    -
    -
    
    2
    . 6
    5.9
    
    6
    2. 8
    21. 6
    
    3
    1. 1
    9- 6
    Total
    
    412
    100%
    100%
    
    405
    100%
    100%
    
    343
    100%
    100%
    
    217
    100%
    100%
    
    260
    100%
    100%
    Source:  1969 Agricultural Census.  Farms with Gross Incomes of $2, 500 or mor<=.
    

    -------
    Total employment would approximate the number of production units and
    consist primarily of family labor.
    
    In states such as Minnesota,  California,  North Carolina and Texas where
    flock sizes are larger,  labor other than family labor would be required.
    Total employment,  therefore, would be approximately two to three Urnes
    greater than the  number of production units.
                                     VIII-14
    

    -------
               II.  TURKEY INDUSTRY FINANCIAL PROFILE
    The focal point of this financial analysis is the farmer growing turkeys
    as an independent producer selling his output to a processor.  Cost data
    used to develop model plants were obtained from several sources with
    primary reliance based on a University of California study,  i'
                          A.  Plants by Segments
    The financial profiles of eight different turkey growers, varying in size
    were  developed for this analyses.  Size of growers varied from production
    of 10,000 birds annually to 200,000 birds.  Growers were assumed to
    brood two hatches of poults annually and  operate at 100 percent capacity.
    Growers purchased all inputs used in each of these model grow-out
    operations.
    
    Annual Profit Before Taxes
    Annual pre-tax net incomes varied among model plants from $5. 00 for
    a producer growing 10,000 birds annually to $18,536 fora producer
    selling 200, 000 birds (Table VIII-4).  Differences in pre-tax income
    was a function of number of birds sold and costs per bird.  Economies
    of scale do exist in turkey production with costs per unit falling rapidly
    up to an output of 20, 000 birds annually.  After a production level of
    20,000 birds has been reached per unit costs are relatively constant.
    
    With the exception  of producers selling 10, 000 birds after tax R. O. I.
    varied from 3.7 to 4. 3  percent increasing as size of grow outs increased.
    
    Average fixed investment on which the above rates  of return were calcu-
    lated,  was derived by dividing replacement costs by two (an estimate of
    average fixed investment)  plus networking capital  (current a s sets) less
    current liabilities.  This average fixed investment  value is intended  to
    approximate  invested capital.
    
    Profitability  of a turkey grower varies greatly as end product prices
    vary and as feed costs fluctuate.   Feed costs represent about two-thirds
    of all va riable costs in producing turkeys.   Variations in prices received
    —  Economies of Scale on California Turkey Production, Eidman, Dean
       and Carter, Giannini Research Report No. 298, August, 1968.
                                  VIII-15
    

    -------
                Table VIII-4.   Estimated pre-tax income and rate of return on average invested capital and
                                   after-tax return on sales for turkey growers,  1971
    Financial Measure
                                                                    Number of Turkeys Started
                                          10,000    20,000    30,000    40,000    50,000   70,000    100,000   200,000
    Pre-tax net income
                                            $5      $1,961    $2,802    $3,351    $4,010    $6,448     9,358   $18,536
    Pre-tax ROI  (%)
    .02
    4.7
    4.8     4.5
                                            4.4
                                                                                              5.3
                                                                                                        5.5      5.5
    After-tax ROI  (%)
                                            -02
    3.7
    3.7     3.5
                                            3.5
                                                                                              4.2
                                                                                                        4.3     4.3
    After-tax return on sales (%)
                                            .01
    1.9
    1.7     1.6
                                            1.5
                                                                                              1.8
                                                                                                        1.8      1.8
    „ Average return on fixed investment calculated by financial statement method.
    

    -------
    of one cent per pound for a grower producing 40,000 birds will cause
    pre-tax income to increase three fold.
    
    Annual Cash Flow
    
    Estimated annual cash flow - after tax income plus depreciation  - and
    the ratio of  cash flow to average fixed investment are  shown in Tables
    VIII-5 and VIII-6.  Depreciation was computed using industry guidelines
    for buildings and equipment.
    
    Annual cash flows varied from $3,054 for the  smaller  model grower
    to $38, 310 for the largest producer.  Cash flow as a percent of average
    investment was  relatively stable varying between  11. 3 and 12. 1 percent.
    
    Market (Salvage) Value of Assets
    
    The salvage value of assets used in turkey grow out operations is some-
    what limited.  Facilities and  equipment used are designed for performing
    specific functions  -  producing turkeys.  This is particuarly true  for
    feeders, waterers,  and  range shelters.  Brooder houses could con-
    ceivably be  converted and used for other poultry or livestock enter-
    prises.  The value of these facilities in alternative uses would vary
    greatly.   For purposes of simplicity we are assuming a salvage  value
    equal to 10 percent of  replacement costs for brooder houses. Salvage
    value for  brood houses for growers producing 40,000 birds annually
    would approximate $12,000.
    
    Capital Structure
    
    Investment required to produce turkeys is a function of the desired  level
    of output (Table VIII-7).  The investment required to  grow-out 10,000
    birds annually is estimated at $43,700, a cost of $4.37 per bird.
    Investment costs increase as the scale of production units increase,
    but not in direct proportion to volume produced.  Investment for a
    200,000 bird operation approximates $550,000,  a cost of $2.76 per
    bird.  Lower  costs per unit of production for larger scale operations
    are a result of internal economics, namely, more intensive use  of
    equipment such as tractors, wagons for delivery, etc.
    
    Cost Structure
    
    Costs for producing turkeys were prepared  to determine the relative
    importance  of various inputs.  Costs were classified into two categories--
    fixed and  variable (Table VIII-8).  Costs for a 40, 000  production unit
    are as follows:
                                  VIII- 17
    

    -------
                    Table VIII-5.  Estimated cash flow for turkey growers, by number of turkeys started, 1971
      Financial Measure
                                                                   Number of Turkeys Started
    10,000   20,000   30,000   40,000   50,000   70,000   100,000   200,000
      Annual cash flow
    $3,054    $5,065   $6,780   $8,348  $10,266  $13,667   $19,226  $38,310
      Cash flow on average fixed
        investment (%)
      12.1
    12. 1    11.7      11.3     11.4     11.4     11.4
    11.4
    1
    h-1
    00
    

    -------
                  Table VIII-6.  Estimated cash flow for turkey growers, by number of turkeys started, 1971
    Number of Birds Started Annually
    
    Utilization (%)!/
    Annual Output - Pounds of
    Turkeys U
    Sales-''
    Variable Expenses
    Feed
    Other
    Fixed Expenses
    Cash Earnings
    Depreciation
    Interest
    Pre-tax Income
    Excluding Family Labor
    Cash Earnings
    Depreciation
    Interest
    Pre-tax Income
    10,000
    100
    180,000
    41,040
    24,458
    10,915
    1,963
    3,704
    3,050
    2,424
    -1,770
    5,479
    3,050
    2,424
    5
    20,000
    100
    360,000
    82,080
    48,854
    21,630
    5,042
    6,554
    3,535
    4,448
    -1,429
    9,944
    3,535
    4,448
    1,961
    30,000
    100
    540,000
    123,120
    73,230
    32,331
    7,275
    10,284
    4,644
    6,228
    -588
    13,674
    4,644
    6,228
    2,802
    40,000
    100
    720,000
    164,160
    97,626
    42,730
    9,672
    14,132.
    5,734
    8,437
    -39
    17,522
    5,734
    8,437
    3,351
    50,000
    100
    900,000
    205,200
    122,033
    53,215
    11,757
    18,195
    7, 138
    10,437
    620
    21,585
    7,138
    10,437
    4,010
    70,000
    100
    1, 260,000
    287,280
    170, 846
    74,075
    16,330
    26,029
    8,637
    14,334
    3,058
    29,419
    8,637
    14,334
    6,448
    100,000
    100
    1,800,000
    410,400
    244,066
    104,870
    23,250
    38,214
    11,926
    20,320
    5,968
    41,604
    11,926
    20,320
    9,358
    200,000
    100
    3,600,000
    820,800
    488,132
    206,650
    46,510
    79,508
    23,852
    40,510
    15,146
    82,898
    23,852
    40,510
    18,536
    _' Two broods per year.
    _' Average weight of turkeys marketed equal 20 pounds each
    2/ Price used was average price received by Western growers,  1971, price = 22. 8^/lb.
    

    -------
                      Table VIII-7.   Estimated replacement value and working capital requirements for turkey
                                     growers, by number of poults started,  1971
      Capital Component
                                                                Number of Poults Started
     10,000    20,000    30,000    40,000   50,000    70,000   100,000   200,000
      Replacement value of
        facilities & equipment
    $43,700   $70,550  $96,100  $122,510  $148,925 $196,470  $275,630   $551,265
      Net working capital
      3,340     6,575    9,695    12,870    15,982   22,172    31,165     60,720
      Replacement value of
       total assets
     47,040    77,125  105,795   135,380   164,907  218,642   306,795    611,985
    tx)
    O
    

    -------
           Table  VIII-8.  Total investment and annual costs of growing turkeys, by number of turkeys started, 1971
    Number Turkeys Started
    
    Total investment - buildings
    and equipment
    Annual Fixed Costs
    Depreciation
    Buildings & Equipment
    Interest
    Taxes, Insurance & Main.
    Toal Fixed Costs
    Annual Variable Costs
    Feed
    Poults
    Medication
    Litter
    Insurance
    Electricity & Fuel
    Machinery Operating Expense
    Inte re s t
    Miscellaneous
    Labor
    Total Variable Costs
    Total Costs
    Total Costs Excluding family
    labor of $3, 390 /year
    10,000
    
    $43,700
    
    
    3,050
    1,009
    1,963
    6,022
    
    24,458
    5,650
    1,940
    220
    440
    430
    210
    1,415
    250
    1,775
    36,788
    42,810
    
    41,035
    20,000
    
    $70,550
    
    
    3, 535
    1,628
    5,042
    10,205
    
    48,854
    11,300
    3,870
    440
    880
    860
    400
    2,820
    490
    3,390
    73,304
    83,509
    
    80, 119
    30, 000
    
    $96, 100
    
    
    4, 644
    2,218
    7,275
    14, 137
    
    73,230
    16,950
    5, 881
    660
    1,325
    1,290
    540
    4,010
    740
    4,945
    109,571
    123,708
    
    120,318
    40,000
    
    $122,510
    
    
    5,734
    2,827
    9,672
    18,233
    
    97,626
    22,600
    7,750
    880
    1,770
    1,710
    650
    5,610
    990
    6,380
    145,966
    164, 199
    
    160,809
    50,000
    
    $148,925
    
    
    7, 138
    3,437
    11,757
    22,332
    
    122, 033
    28,250
    9,690
    1, 105
    2,210
    2, 145
    780
    7,000
    1,235
    7,800
    182,248
    204,580
    
    201, 190
    70,000
    
    $196,470
    
    
    8,637
    4,534
    16,330
    29,501
    
    170,846
    39,550
    13,560
    1,550
    3,090
    3,015
    1,050
    9,800
    1,730
    10,530
    254,721
    284,222
    
    280,832
    100, 000
    
    $275,630
    
    
    11,926
    6,360
    23,250
    41,536
    
    244,066
    56,500
    19,370
    2,210
    4,420
    4,290
    1,450
    13,960
    2,470
    14, 160
    362,896
    404,432
    
    401,042
    200,000
    
    $551,265
    
    
    23,852
    12,720
    46,510
    83,082
    
    488, 132
    113,000
    38,740
    4,420
    3,840
    8,680
    2,830
    27,790
    4, 940
    25,200
    722,572
    805,654
    
    $802,264
    Source: Investment and cost of production data were obtained from the following sources and modied to reflect costs in 1971.
            A Comparison of Returns to Poultry Growers, U.S.D.A., E.R.S., Ma rketing Resea rch Report No. 814, Feb. 1968
            Economies of Scale on California Turkey Production, V.  P.  Kidman,  G. W. Dean,  and H. O. Carter, California
            Agricultural Experiment Station, Giannine Foundation Research Report  No.  298, August, 1968.
    

    -------
                   Annual Fixed Costs           Dollars        Percent
    
                    Depreciation                  5,734         3.5
                    Interest                      2,827         1.7
                    Taxes,  Insurance  &          9,672         5.9
                        Maintenance
                      Total  Fixed                 18,233        11. 1
    
                   Annual Variable
                    Feed~               97,626        59.5
                    Poults                       22,600        13.8
                    Other                        25,740        15.7
                    Total Variable Costs        145,966        88.9
    
                   Total Costs                $164,199       100.0
    
    The most significant costs are feed and poult expenses which account
    for 59. 5 and 13.8 percent of all costs,  respectively (Table VIII-8).
    Generally,  costs equal 98 percent of total sales varying as end product
    and feed cost fluctuates  (Table VIII-9).
    
    
                   B.   Ability to  Finance New Investment
    Generally, turkey growers have relied upon the Production Credit
    Association, Farmers Home Administration, feed companies, turkey
    processors and private financial institutions as  sources of capital.   The
    willingness of these financial institutions to finance turkey growers is
    dependent upon  the ability of growers to pay back capital loans.  During
    periods of "good" turkey prices, financing is readily available.  During
    depressionary periods, availability of capital for new or expansion of
    existing facilities is curtailed.
    
    In view of today's situation with high feed  prices and  ceilings on retail
    prices of turkeys, the  availability of capital for financing turkey growers
    is probably limited.  Growers, without some type of  production contract
    are probably operating with a negative cash flow and  lack the ability to
    repay capital  investments.  They are poor credit risks.
                                    VIII-22
    

    -------
                          Table VIJJ-9.   Estimated costs for turkey growers, by number of poults started, 1971 .
    
    
                        	Number of Poults Started           	
      Item               I'D, 000        20,000         30,000          40,000        50,000   :     70,000          100,000
                        |     %      $%$%       |      %      $%|     %       $% —
    
    Sales            41,040 100    82,080 100    123,120  100    164,160  100   205,200  100  .287,280 100   410,400  100
    
    Raw materials    30,108 73.4   60,154 73.3    90,180 73.2   120,226  73.2  150,283 73.2  210,396 73.2  300,566 73.2
    
    
    Direct operating   4,905 11-9    9,760 11.9    16,001 13.0    22,345  13.6   28,575 13.9   40,935 14.2   58,940 14.4
      cost
    
    Indirect operating  1,963  4.7    5,042  6.1     7,275  5.9     9,672   5.9   11,757  5.7   16,330  5.6   23,250   5.7
      cost
    
    Depreciation      3,050  7.4    3,535  4.3     4,644  3.8     5,734   3.5    7,138  3.5    8,637  3.0   11,926   2.9
    
    Interest           1,009  2.5    1,628  2.0     2,218  1.8     2,827   1.7    3,437  1.7    4,534  1.6    6,360   1.6
    
    Total before-     41,035 99-9   80,119 97.6   120,318 97.7   160,809  97.9  201,190 98.0  280,832 97.6  401,042 97.7
      tax cost
    

    -------
                    PART IX:  THE DUCK INDUSTRY
                     I.  DUCK INDUSTRY SEGMENTS
                           A .   Types of Firms
    The number of ducks raised annually in the United States has increased
    slightly during the past two decades.  The Census of Agriculture reported
    13 million ducks raised in 1969 compared to about 10 million in 1949.
    
                                               Ducks Raised
                         Year                  million head
    
                         1969                      13.0
                         1964                      12.5
                         1959                      12.2
                         1954                      11.1
                         1949                      10.3
    
                   Source:  U. S. Census  of Agriculture
    
    Number and Volume of  Product Units
    
    Production of ducks is concentrated in five states which produce about
    90 percent of all ducks.   These states  include New York,  Indiana,  Wis-
    consin, California and Illinois.  New York is the major producing area
    accounting for about 60 percent of U.S. production.  Production in New
    York is concentrated in the Long Island area.
    
    In the five  leading duck producing states there were  147 farms with ducks
    (Table IX-1).   Of the total number of farms,  79 were classified as Class I
    farms  by the Census Bureau.  These farms have gross farm incomes of
    $40,000 or more annually. Farms  of this  size, in these five  states, ac-
    counted for nearly all production.
    
    Production
    The number of ducks federally inspected has been relatively constant
    during the period of I960 to 1971  (Table IX-2).  In 1971,  slightly over
    11 million ducks were slaughtered under federal inspection.  Liveweight
    and pounds certified as ready-to-cook birds were 69,341 and 49,413
    thousand pounds, respectively.
                                    IX-1
    

    -------
          Table  IX-1.  Number of farms producing ducks and ducks sold,  five
                                      leading states, 1969
    State
    New York
    Indiana
    Wisconsin
    California
    Illinois
    All
    No. Farms
    53
    32
    33
    17
    12
    147
    Farms
    Ducks Sold
    (1,000)
    6,096
    2,965
    1,453
    764
    633
    11,911
    Clasp I
    No. Farms
    34
    24
    9
    8
    4
    79
    Farms1 /
    Ducks Sold
    (1,000)
    6,073
    2,899
    1,437
    763
    628
    11 , 800
    Average No.
    z/
    Sold Per Farm
    178,600
    120,790
    159,660
    95,370
    157,000
    149,360
    
    
    
    
    
    —  Farms with sales of $40,000 or more annually.
    
    ^/ Class I farms.
                                             IX-2
    

    -------
      Table IX-2. Number and pounds of ducks federally inspected,
                          liveweight, U.S., I960 to 1972
    Year
    1971
    1970
    1969
    1968
    1967
    1966
    1965
    1964
    1963
    1962
    1961
    I960
    Number
    Inspected
    (1,000)
    11,030
    11,883
    11,589
    10,257
    10,133
    10,496
    10,455
    10,714
    10,368
    9,344
    9,626
    10,086
    Pounds
    Inspected
    Liveweight
    / 1 nnn
    69,341
    74,042
    72,018
    64,745
    64,262
    66,895
    66,797
    68,206
    66,090
    59,611
    60,503
    62,287
    Pounds
    Certified
    Ready -to -cook
    1V.O \
    49,413
    52,617
    51, 133
    46,369
    45,937
    47,928
    47,898
    48,395
    46,865
    42,084
    42, 504
    44,385
    Source: Agricultural Statistics, U.S.,  I960 to 1972.
                                       IX-3
    

    -------
    Level of Technology
    
    No known studies are available on the  level of technology employed in
    the  production of ducks.  The average sales per production unit are
    large, averaging 150,000 birds each.  To produce this volume of birds
    on individual units  probably necessitates  the use of available current
    technology in feeding rations,  handling of feed,  preventative  disease
    practices, etc.
    
    Level of Integration
    
    It is assumed that duck production is a highly integrated industry -with
    individual producers or  cooperatives maintaining breeding flocks,
    hatching eggs, raising ducklings to market  weight and processing
    mature ducks.  The  size of individual  producing units would justify
    an integrated approach to duck production.
    
    Feedstuffs Magazine in their September 4,  1972 edition, reported on a
    fully  integrated operation located in Indiana.  This one firm produced
    16 percent of U.S.  production.   This firm grew 300,000 ducklings on it's
    own facilities with  the remainder being raised by 20  growers located in
    adjacent areas .  These growers produced birds under contract. A con-
    tract grower furnishes the facilities and labor in the operation. The
    contractor furnishes ducks,  feed,  medication and supervision.  The
    growers are compensated through three plans:   one  is by the bird,
    another is by the pound, and the third  is an incentive program  for feed
    and mortality efficiency.
    
    Comment
    
    Lack of data pertaining to duck production prevents a complete description
    of the industry and the development of costs and investments in production
    units. If data is located a more complete analysis will be provided.
                                    IX-4
    

    -------
                       PART X:  GENERAL PRICING
                         A.  Price Determination
    Most segments of the feedlot industry are comprised of many producers,
    each producing so small a portion of the total supply that they are unable
    to independently influence the prices they receive.  The possible exception
    is duck growers.  Here a small number of producers supply the nation's
    ducks.  Some duck operations are totally integrated, growing, processing
    and distributing their product.  In the case of at least one large duck
    grower, who supplies  16% of U.  S.  duck  supply, this grower contracts
    with other duck producers to provide birds for his integrated operation.
    
    Although dairy farmers cannot independently influence prices received,
    many have joined in forming milk marketing  cooperatives which serve  as
    the bargaining representative of producers and may also be involved in
    milk processing.  In addition,  Federal and State programs directly or
    indirectly affect the pricing of milk sold by farmers.  Two Federal pro-
    grams are concerned with pricing and marketing milk.  The Federal
    Milk Marketing Order program provides for  the establishment of marketing
    orders  to regulate the terms under  which milk dealers, selling milk within
    a specified geographic area, purchase milk from farmers.   These orders
    require that dealers pay farmers a  specified minimum price based upon
    the use of milk.  Milk for fluid use  is placed in Class I, the  highest
    priced class.   This  class generally includes  whole  milk,  skim, low fat
    milk, milk drinks, flavored milk, and buttermilk.
    
    Class II milk,  that not used in Class I, is priced at levels approximating the
    prices paid at unregulated plants that manufacture dairy products such as
    butter and cheese.   Farmers receive a weighted average  or  "blend price"
    for milk that reflects the amount of milk used for fluid consumption and for
    manufacturing purposes.   In 1971, there were 62 Federal orders handling
    81 percent of all fluid  milk sales in the U.S.  compared with  50 percent in
    1950.
    
    The  dairy price support program, the second federal program, provides
    for the  U. S.D. A. to set a national average support price  for manufacturing
    milk based upon a Minnesota-Wisconsin price series.  This  price series
    reflects the value of milk used in manufactured products.  At present this
    support price is  $5. 29 per hundred  weight.   This support price is used to
    calculate  Class I prices for all market orders.  The differential by which
    the Class I price exceeds the Minnesota-Wisconsin price  is  determined for
    each market based on  several factors.  These factors include the added
    cost of producing milk eligible for fluid use (Grade A), costs of transportating
    supplies from producing areas,  supply and demand conditions in the market,
    and other economic factors.  The differential between Class II, (^ianufacturing)
    
                                      X-l
    

    -------
    milk and Class I generally increases with distance from the Minnesota-
    Wisconsin area.  For example, the differential equalled $1. 06 per cwt.
    for the Minneapolis-St. Paul order in December,  1971 and $3. 07 in the
    Corpus Christie, Texas order.
    
    In addition to the Federal programs some states have milk control
    programs.  The authority of these programs vary from setting producer,
    wholesale and retail prices to establishing t^ade practice  regulations.
    (Figure X-l and Table X -1)
    
    Previously mentioned bargaining cooperatives frequently have been able
    to negotiate minimum Class I prices exceeding Federally established prices.
    It  is estimated that eight large federations of milk marketing cooperatives
    control over forty percent of the nations  milk supply.
    
    Cattle, hogs and sheep are  all marketed  in a different fashion.  Producers of
    all three price takers who market  their livestock  either  through  terminal
    markets,  auction markets,  or sell directly to packers or a  country dealer.
    The trend is toward selling directly to the packer or a country dealer
    and away  from the terminal market.  Over 2/3 packer purchases of live-
    stock were through direct purchase and country dealers.  Slightly more than
    15 percent through terminal markets and the remainder  through  auction
    markets.  While auction markets have remained stable or declined  slightly,
    considerable shifts have occurred between terminal and direct or county
    dealer marketing.  Since 1963 the  percent marketed at terminal  markets
    have declined 23.2, 9-7, and 16.3 percent for cattle, hogs and sheep,
    respectively.   Generally, this loss to the terminal has gone to direct
    marketing.  Livestock producers are price takers because no producer
    is large enough to independently influence the market and because live-
    stock producers  still act independently in marketing their  product.  Large
    producers may be able to negotiate prices with the packer somewhat when
    selling directly, but  the bargaining power of the  seller  is generally low
    as the packer can still buy  elsewhere.
    
    Area differences in prices are related to differences in transportation cost
    and local  demand and supply situations.  Higher livestock prices are ex-
    pected in  deficit red  meat producing regions.
    
    Turkey, broiler, and egg producers operate in similar market environments.
    In all three instances, contract production is  more  common than selling on
    the open market.  In each case,  the industry is  made up of many producers
    who are not able to influence the market  price.  Over 60 percent
    duction is on contract basis.  Many of the independent producers process
    and distribute their own eggs.
                                      X-2
    

    -------
    X
              STATES REGULATING  FLUID MILK PRICES
                                 January I, 1972
             STATES REGULATING:
    
                 SALES BELOW COST
    
                 PRODUCER PRICES
    
                 RESALE PRICES
    
                 PRODUCER AND RESALE PRICES
                                   Figure X-l.
    

    -------
    Table X-l.  States  regulating milk prices and trade practices and
            authorizing milk promotion,  January 1972.
    State
    Alabama
    Arkansas
    California
    Colorado
    Connecticut
    Georgia
    Hawaii
    Idaho
    Iowa
    Kentucky
    Louisiana
    Maine
    Massachusetts
    Minnesota
    Missouri
    Montana
    Nebraska
    Nevada
    New Hampshire
    New Jersey
    New York
    North Carolina
    North Dakota
    Oklahoma
    Ohio
    Oregon
    Pennsylvania
    South Carolina
    South Dakota
    Tennessee
    Utah
    Vermont
    Virginia
    Washington
    West Virginia
    Wisconsin
    Wyoming
    Puerto Rico
    Minimum prices
    established at—
    Producer
    level
    X
    —
    X
    —
    —
    —
    X
    —
    —
    —
    X
    X
    X
    —
    —
    X
    —
    X
    —
    X
    X
    X
    X
    —
    —
    (»)
    X
    X
    —
    —
    —
    X
    X
    —
    —
    —
    X
    X
    Whole-
    sale
    level
    X
    —
    X
    —
    —
    —
    —
    —
    —
    —
    X
    X
    (O
    —
    —
    X
    —
    X
    —
    X
    —
    (')
    X
    —
    —
    —
    X
    X
    X
    —
    —
    X
    'X
    —
    —
    —
    X
    'X
    Retail
    level
    'X
    —
    X
    —
    —
    —
    —
    —
    —
    —
    X
    X
    (>)
    —
    —
    X
    —
    X
    —
    X
    —
    (>)
    'X
    —
    —
    —
    X
    X
    X
    —
    —
    X
    'X
    —
    —
    —
    —
    'X
    Trade
    practice
    regulations
    X
    X
    X
    X
    X
    —
    —
    X
    X
    X
    X
    X
    X
    X
    X
    X
    X
    X
    —
    X
    X
    X
    X
    X
    —
    —
    —
    X
    X
    X
    —
    X
    X
    —
    —
    X
    X
    X
    Milk
    promotion
    _
    —
    X
    X
    X
    X
    'X
    X
    —
    —
    X
    X
    4X
    Jx
    —
    —
    —
    ~
    X
    X
    'X
    —
    X
    —
    Jx
    X
    'X
    —
    X
    —
    X
    X
    —
    X
    X
    X
    —
    X
     X = yes, - = No.
     1 Also establishes maximum prices
     1 Industrywide agreement on Oahu coordinated by State.
     3 Authorized but not used
     4 The Milk Control Law states "  . :o promote pro-ams designed to increase the consump-
    tion of milk."
     'The  State's Class I b reoooi Oregon-Washington Federal milk order pro-
    ducer payments :f requested by individual Oregon producers
                                        X-4
    

    -------
    The price an individual grower receives for growing broilers is determined
    by contractors.  Their choices are limited to making decisions to either
    grow or not grow broilers and then what contractor they wish to work with.
    The typical arrangement is for a grower to supply housing,  feeders,
    waterers,  utilities and labor.  The contractor will supply the birds,
    feed,  medications and supervisory assistance.  In essence, a grower
    rents facilities to  a contractor.   The rent  received is a predetermined
    amount per pound  of broilers grown, and may vary by efficiency  standards.
    These  standards may include feed conversion, mortality rates,  rate of
    condemnation,  etc.  The more efficient growers will receive a bonus
    above the predetermined rate per pound.   Less efficient growers are
    penalized by  reducing  their  payment per pound.
    
    The price, or gross receipts, received by a turkey producer is dependent
    upon the  type of production or marketing arrangement with a processor.
    The returns to a grow and the risks involved will vary by  type of contract.
    
           - Production payment contract
    
                 Contractor's (integrations) pay producers a  stipulated
                 amount per pound for turkeys marketed.  Amount paid
                 may vary relative to aspects of performance such as
                 mortality and feed efficiency.
    
           - Floor price contract
    
                 Growers own the birds, assume all  production risks, and
                 shares price risk with the contractor.  The  producer, in
                 turn, receives a price which is no lower than a fixed minimum
                 (floor)  or at a schedule of prices related to market  prices.
                 In this  type of contract a grower trades part of his potential
                 profit if market prices are high for  a guaranteed floor price,
                 if they ar e low.
    
           - Marketing contract
    
                 A contractor agrees to process and  market a producers birds
                 and to return to him the net proceeds above  processing, storage
                 and other costs.
    
           - Financing contracts
    
                 A grower owns the  birds and assumes all production and
                 price risks.  In return for contractor financing of turkey
                 production,  the grower agrees to buy the contractor's feed
                 and/or sell the finished birds to the contractor.
                                      X-5
    

    -------
                               B.  Demand
    
    1.   Retail
    Trends in per capita consumption of livestock and poultry products are
    shown for the years 1950-1971 in Figures X-Z and X-3.  Consumption  of beef
    and poultry has increased considerably during this period.  Neither com-
    modity shows significant divergence in recent years.  Decline in per
    capita consumption in 1971 is the result of insufficient supply as can be
    seen by the rise in retail prices of beef.   The beef consumption tiend
    when observed with the  rising retail price trend indicates that the  demand
    curve  for beef has been shifting outward as a result  of not only increases
    in consumer income but also shifts in consumer preference for beef.
    
    Chicken consumption, on the other hand, has been heavily influenced by
    declining retail prices for chickens.  Retail price of chickens  have fallen
    from near $.60/lb in the early 50's to $.43/lb in 1971.   During the same
    time per  capita consumption doubled  going from Z0.6 Ibs in 1950 to 41.6
    Ibs in  1971.  The price  elasticity of demand for chicken is - .777 .  A
    23 percent increase in quantity consumed would result from a 30 percent
    decline in price indicating that although price decline was important,  it
    explained less  than one-fourth of the  increase in consumption.  The
    remaining increase is associated mainly with increases  in consumer
    income.
    
    Pork consumption has tended to decline since  1950.  However, some of
    the loss has been recouped beginning in 1969.   However, per capita con-
    sumption still remains below 1950-1952 consumption.  Pork prices have
    increased during this  period from $.50 per Ib in 1950 to $.687 per Ib in
    1971.   Change  in consumer  preference away from pork along •with  increases
    in retail pork prices account for the decline in consumption.  With the small
    income elasticity (almost zero), increased consumption resulting  from higher
    consumer incomes could not offset the  impact of the former factors.
    
    Per  capita consumption of eggs has declined from 37.9 Ibs  in  1950 to
    34.7 Ibs in  1971 (Figure X-2).  Egg prices have declined moderately
    during the same period  (Figure X-4).   The income elasticity is close to
    zero.   King and  George  _'   detected a statistically  significant negative time
    trend of more than 5 percent per year in the consumption of eggs.   This time
    trend  reflects changes in eating habits  and the  reduced appeal of eggs be-
    cause  of the general recognition of the  high cholesterol content of  eggs.  Most
    eggs are  purchased as shell eggs with many of the shell eggs  used for
    breakfast.  Declines in  the percent of households eating  breakfast  plus the
    growth of convenience foods have resulted in the erosion of the consumption
    of shell eggs.  The consumption of processed eggs or eggs  incorporated in
    _' George,  P, S. and G. A.  King.   Consume r_ Demand for Food Commodities
       in the U.S. with Proje^ lions for  TWO",  Giannirii  FTnmdTtTorT"Mbno gTaph
       #26,~Ma~rch,  1971,  University of Calif.
    
                                     X-6
    

    -------
     84
    
    
    
    
     80
    
    
    
    
     76
    
    
    
    
     72
    
    
    
    
     68
    
    
    
    
     64
    
    
    
    
     60
    
    
    
    
     56
    
    
    
    
     52
    2 48
    cu
    a
    
    en
    44
    
    
    
    
    40
    
    
    
    
    36
    
    
    
    
    32
    
    
    
    
    28
    
    
    
    
    24
    
    
    
    
    20
                                                                Beef
                                                              Pork
                                                                 Eggs
    
                                                                 Chickens
                                                                      Turkey
         51    53    55   57    59   61    63    65
    
    
    Figure X-2.  Per Capita Consumption   X-7
                                                         67    69
    

    -------
    Pounds per capita
         330
         320
    
         310
    
    
         300
    
    
         290
    
    
         280
    
         270
    
    
         260
    
    
         250
    
    
         240
          X
        20 -
                                    Fluid milk
           10
            0
                                	Ice c_reaiu	__	
                                      Butter
                                     _L
                                             _L
                                                            J.
                                                            1970
                                                                   1980
            Year      1955        I960        1965
    Figure X-3.  Per  capita consumption of selected dairy products in the
                 U.S. for selected years  1954-1972,  with a forecast to 1980.
    
                 Note:  1972 Data are preliminary
                        Fluid milk consumption is based  on the product weight
                        of the  Economics Research Service, USDA Research Series.
    Source:  George, P.S. and G. A. King.  Consumer Demand for Food
             Commodities in the U.S.  with Projections for 1980, Giannini
             Foundation  Monograph #26, March, 1971, University of  California.
                                         X-t
    

    -------
       100
    
    
      96.5 •
    
      93. 0
    
      89.5
    
      86.0 •
    
      82. 5 •
    
      79. 0
    
      75. 5
    
      72. 0 •
    "0
    §68.5
    0,
    
    £65.0
    CO
    
    £61. 5
      58.0
    
      54. 5
    
      51. 0
    
      47.5
    
      44. 0
    
      40.5
    
      37. 0
    
      33.5
    
    
      30. 0
            Beef
          .• Chicken
            Eggs
                 51    53    55    57    59    61    63    65    67
            Figure X-4.   Retail Price of Meats and Poultry     X-9
    69
    71
    

    -------
    other food items has increased, but the increase is small compared with
    the decline in shell egg consumption.
    
    Turkey consumption increased from 4. 1 Ibs in  1950 to 8.5 Ibs in 1971.
    With the limited price data available,  indications are that turkey prices
    have increased moderately.  The price  elasticity of demand for turkey
    is -1.55 indicating that a percentage increase in price will result in
    more than an equal percentage decline in consumption.  The demand
    for turkey is relatively more income elastic than most food items having
    a value of 0.768.  Additionally, the development and acceptance by consumers
    of frozen turkeys and frozen turkey products have  increased turkey con-
    sumption by  slightly reducing the seasonality of the product.
    
    Trends in the consumption of dairy products are mixed (Figure  X-3).  A
    general decline in per capita consumption of fluid milk consumption since
    1955 stopped in 1972.  Consumption of evaporated milk continues  to decline.
    Ice cream consumption remains stable at just under 20 pounds per person.
    Cheese consumption has increased, with a  continuous upward trend since
    I960 and an acceleration since 1971.  The latter is attributed to the sub-
    stitution of cheese for meat  in the  face of high meat prices.  Consumer
    demand for all dairy products has  diminished slightly.
    
    Lamb and mutton consumption remains  low.  Present consumption is about
    4 Ib per person while per capita consumption has fallen slightly.  No data
    is available on consumption  and retail prices of ducks.  However,
    production has increased from 54 million Ibs in 1959 to 69 million Ibs in
    1971.  Per capita consumption is about one-fourth pound.
    
    2.  Demand Projections
    
    Some leveling off of the  demand for beef is expected.  However, con-
    sumption is closely tied to production and if production increased to the
    point where retail price retreated  from recent  levels, additional con-
    sumption would be  expected. Pork consumption per capita appears to have
    leveled off and demand for pork will shift with population increases.  A ten
    to fourteen percent increase in population is  expected between 1970 and 1980
    based on official projections.—
    
    Present consumption of chicken already exceeds George and King's estimate
    of 39 Ibs for 1980 — .  With  some moderating of present trends per capita con-
    sumption could reach 45 Ibs. by 1980.  Egg consumption is declining at
    L' Bureau of Census, Department of Commerce, "Population Estimates and
       Projections," Current Population Reports No. 470,  November, 1971.
    — George and King, p.  98,  op.  cit.
                                     X-10
    

    -------
    a declining rate and George and King's estimate of 41 Ibs per person
    in 1980 appears fairly reasonable.  This would mean only a slight decline
    in egg consumption.  Turkey consumption has shown a steady increase
    and will approach 10 Ibs per capita by  1980.  Lamb and mutton consumption
    is expected to continue to decline from the 1962-66 average of 3.9 Ibs to
    3. 1 Ibs in 1980.
    
    Based on recent trends, per capita consumption of fluid milk can be
    expected to decline to about 265-270 pounds per year by  1980.  The con
    sumption of American cheese, however, has been increasing over the past
    decade and is projected to a consumption level of about 14 pounds by  1980.
    
    Estimated consumption of evaporated milk is based on a  negative time  trend
    and no income effect.  Evaporated milk was projected  at 5 pounds per capita
    by 1980, close to what would be obtained from a simple time trend.   Esti-
    mated consumption of ice cream for 1980 based on an income coefficient
    is 20 pounds. Projected  consumption for butter in 1980 is 4.9 pounds.  This
    is based on a positive income elasticity and a negative time trend which
    indicates a change in preference away from butter.
    
    Another significant  trend has been that of increasing cottage cheese con-
    sumption.  This has probably been due in large part to the desire of
    many people  to take off or keep off weight by eating low-fat products.
    Cottage cheese is also a cheap source of protein.
    
    A  10-14 percent increase in civilian population from 1970 to 1980 is assumed
    to occur.  The demand for beef is  expected to show strong increases with
    combined effect of shifting demand on a per capita basis  and continued
    population growth.   For pork  increases in  total demand will result almost
    wholly from population increase.   Per capita demand for eggs is expected
    to decline less on a  percentage basis than population.  Thus,  total egg
    consumption should  not change greatly.  The demand for chickens has
    shifted to the right,  but not all of the increase in consumption is attributed
    to shifting demand.  Retail price fell during 1950-1971 resulting in movement
    along the demand curve as well as shifting outward.  Combined with population
    growth total  chicken demand should increase , but less than for beef.   Turkey
    demand will  shift outward with both per capita consumption and population
    increasing.   Insufficient data  is available to project  demand for ducks,
    however, it is expected that any increases  will atbest be geared to
    population increases.
                                      X-ll
    

    -------
    In 1965, 124. 2 billion Ibs of milk were produced.  Production fell to
    116. 1 billion Ibs in 1969 and turned up to 118.6 billion Ibs in 1971.
    Comparing dairy product consumption projections, which indicate a
    slight decline in per capita use of all dairy products with projected
    population increase indicates that use of milk for all dairy products
    will range from  remaining constant to increasing slightly.
    
    3.  Farm  Level Demand Elasticities
    
    Price elasticity of demand for livestock and poultry products are  more
    inelastic at the farm level than the  retail level.  Price elasticities of
    demand for the products in question are as  follows:
    
                                                Price Elasticity of
                                                Demand-Farm  Levels
    Beef
    Pork
    Lamb and mutton
    Chickens
    Turkey
    Eggs
    Milk
    Duck
    Source: George, P. S. and G. A. King.
    for Food Commodities in the U.
    -0.416
    -0.241
    -1.670
    -0.602
    N.A.
    -0.225
    -0.323
    
    
    
    
    
    N.A.
    Consumer Demand
    S. with
    Projections
                       for 1980,  Giannini Foundation Monograph #26,
                       March, 1971.  University of California.
    
    The demand for lamb and mutton is most responsive to price  changes at
    the farm level.  A one percent increase in price reduces the quantity
    demanded by 1.67  percent.  Chickens are next  with a price elasticity of
    -0.602.  Price elasticity of demand for beef, at the  farm level,  is
    -0.416, indicating that a one percent decline in price would result in a
    0.4 percent  increase in quantity demanded.  With inelastic demand co-
    efficients a small decrease in the quantity offered by producers will
    result in a large percentage increase in price at the farm level.
                                    X-12
    

    -------
                                C.   Supply
    
    Cattle feedlots are only one  segment of the beef industry.  Cow-calf
    operations and the size of breeding herds determine the number of cattle
    that will be available at any  point in time for feeding in feedlots.  The
    number of fed cattle slaughtered is a function of production decisions
    made by brood-cow calf producers two years in the past.
    
    The major changes in the beef industry during the post World War II
    period has been the increase in the proportion of fed beef and in the size
    and number of commercial feedlots.   Since  1962,  the number of feedlots
    with capacity of 8, 000 head or more has  tripled.  With the shift toward
    the large commercial feedlot, the  feedlots are more sensitive to input
    prices such as feed and feeder cattle than the general  farmer who  raises
    his own feed and feeder cattle.
    
    The cattle cycle is an important characteristic of the beef industry re-
    sulting from the large time period required to complete production.
    Cattle production  and prices tend to follow 10-12 year cycles.   During a
    period of high prices, feeders bid up feeder cattle prices which, with
    some lag in adjustment, encourages the cow-calf  operations to save more
    calves for breeding stock so as to increase  production.  With the  long
    time required to make  the adjustment, there is a  tendency to overproduce
    which is not  recognized until the oversupply reaches the retail level.  At
    this point the reverse process operates.   The result is a cycling of pro-
    duction and prices with prices inversely  related to production.
    
    Production cycling and general  expansion of the supply to meet increasing
    consumer demand can be seen in Table X-2.
    
    Hog production is shifting from the farm lot to confinement feeding.  Con-
    finement feeding operations  are  usually of larger  size than the average  farm
    lot operation.  Still, a  large portion of the hogs are  raised in open lots
    which requires less capital investment.  Typical farm lot hog  production
    in the past had two farrowings,  spring and fall,  with the former being
    the larger.  Confinement feeding with higher investment costs encourages
    producers to practice continuous farrowings in order to more  fully utilize
    their facilities.
    
    Hog production tends to cycle as in the case for beef.  However, the cycle
    is much  shorter,  about four years. The shorter cycle is attributed to the
    shorter production period involved.  Confinement producers will tend
    
                                    X-13
    

    -------
    Table X-2.  Marketings of livestock and poultry,  liveweight basis,  1950 to 1972,  U.S.
    Beef
    Year
    
    
    1971
    1970
    1969
    1968
    1967
    1966
    1965
    1964
    1963
    1962
    1961
    1960
    1959
    1958
    1957
    195b
    1955
    1954
    1953
    1952
    1951
    1950
    Sales
    live wt.
    billion
    pounds
    40. 6
    39- 5
    37. 1
    36.4
    35. 9
    35. 0
    34.0
    34. 8
    32. 8
    30. 8
    29. 9
    28. 8
    28. 3
    26. 8
    26. 6
    27. 5
    28. 1
    27.6
    27.4
    24. 9
    23. 0
    21. 2
    Average
    Price
    All Cattle
    per/cwt.
    
    $36.
    34.
    31.
    27.
    26.
    26.
    22.
    20.
    24.
    25.
    23.
    22.
    26.
    25.
    18.
    16.
    16.
    16.
    16.
    25.
    31.
    26.
    
    ,30
    , 50
    . 50
    , 60
    , 30
    00
    .00
    40
    00
    10
    70
    90
    70
    30
    70
    10
    80
    50
    70
    80
    90
    30
    Pork
    Sales
    live wt.
    billion
    pounds
    22.9
    22.9
    20. 5
    21. 1
    20. 6
    19. 1
    18. 1
    20. 2
    21.0
    20.3
    20.2
    19. 2
    21. 3
    19. 2
    18.4
    19- 1
    20. 2
    18. 2
    16. 8
    19.7
    21.4
    20. 2
    Average
    Price
    All hogs
    per/cwt.
    
    $17.50
    22.70
    22. 20
    18. 50
    18. 90
    22. 80
    20.60
    14. 80
    14.90
    16. 30
    16. 60
    15. 30
    14. 10
    19. 60
    17. 80
    14.40
    15. 00
    21. 60
    21.40
    17. 80
    20. 00
    18.00
    Lamb & mutton
    Sales
    live wt .
    billion
    pounds
    1. 0
    1. 1
    1. 0
    1. 1
    1. 1
    1. 2
    1.2
    1. 3
    1.4
    1. 5
    1.6
    1. 6
    1. 7
    1. 7
    1. 5
    1. 6
    1.6
    1.6
    1. 5
    1. 5
    1.4
    1. 3
    Average
    Price
    lambs
    per/cwt.
    
    $25.90
    26.40
    27. 20
    24.40
    22. 10
    23.40
    22.80
    19.90
    18.10
    17.85
    15.80
    17.90
    18.70
    21.00
    19-90
    18.50
    18.40
    19-10
    19. 30
    24. 30
    31.00
    25. 10
    Turkeys
    Sales
    live wt,
    billion
    pounds
    2. 3
    2. 2
    2. 0
    2. 0
    2. 3
    2. 1
    1. 9
    1. 8
    1. 7
    1. 6
    1.9
    1. 5
    1. 4
    1.4
    1.4
    1.3
    1. 1
    1. 2
    1. 0
    1. 0
    1. 0
    0. 8
    Average
    Price
    . turkeys
    per Ib.
    
    22. If
    22. 6
    22.4
    20. 5
    19. 7
    23. 1
    22. 1
    21.0
    22. 3
    21. 6
    18. 9
    25. 4
    23. 9
    23. 9
    23. 4
    27. 2
    30. 2
    28. 8
    33. 7
    33.6
    7. 5
    32.9
    Broilers
    Sales
    live wt.
    billion
    pounds
    10. 8
    10. 8
    10.0
    9.3
    9- 2
    9. 0
    8. 1
    7. 5
    7. 3
    6.9
    6. 8
    6. 0
    5. 8
    5.4
    4. 7
    4.3
    3.4
    3. 2
    2. 9
    2. 6
    2.4
    1. 9
    Average
    Price
    broilers
    per Ib.
    Eggs
    Average
    Sales Price
    live wt eggs
    billion cents/lb.
    pounds
    13. 7£
    13.6
    15. 2
    14. 2
    13. 3
    15. 3
    15. 0
    14. 2
    14. 6
    15. 2
    13.9
    16.9
    16.1
    18. 5
    18. 9
    19.6
    25. 2
    23. 1
    27. 1
    28.8
    28. 5
    27.4
    9.4
    9- 1
    9.0
    9.0
    9.1
    8.7
    8.6
    8. 5
    8.3
    8. 3
    8. 1
    8.0
    8. 3
    8. 0
    8. 0
    8. 0
    7. 8
    7.7
    7. 6
    7. 6
    7.6
    7.7
    '31.4
    39-1
    40.0
    34.0
    3-1.2
    39-1
    33.7
    33. 8
    34.5
    33.8
    35. 6
    36.1
    31.4
    38. 5
    35.9
    39-3
    39.5
    36.6
    47.7
    41.6
    47.7
    36. 3
    Ducks
    Sales
    live wt.
    million
    pounds
    69
    74
    72
    65
    64
    67
    67
    68
    66
    60
    61
    62
    54
    NA
    n
    •'
    ||
    1 1
    ii
    ti
    M
    n
    Average
    Price
    ducks
    
    
    NA
    ii
    ii
    n
    n
    n
    n
    n
    n
    ii
    n
    ii
    ii
    n
    it
    ||
    ||
    tt
    n
    n
    n
    n
    

    -------
    to operate near full capacity as long as receipts cover variable costs.
    In times of high prices new producers enter production and then exit
    as prices fall.
    
    Production systems for broilers, eggs, turkeys, and ducks are similar.
    These four segments are highly coordinated industries.  Most production
    occurs with producers  entering into either production and/or marketing
    agreements with  processors.  Production is becoming concentrated in
    large units.
    
    The  supply of broilers  has steadily increased during the past two  decades.
    In 1950,  631  million birds were produced increasing to 1.795 million in
    I960 and equalling over 3.0 billion  birds in 1972.  These increases in supply
    occurred even though the farm price for  broilers was decreasing  from about
    27 cents per pound in 1950 to 14.2 cents  in 1972.  The use of new technology
    resulted in increased efficiency and provided producers with a profit as
    farm prices  declined.
    
    The  supply of eggs decreased in 1972 after expanding during the sixties.
    Total production in 1972 equalled 5,791 million dozens,  a decrease of
    one percent from 1971. The total supply of eggs from  1965  to 1972 are
    as follows:
    
                                         Eggs Produced
                  Year                   Million Dozen
    
                   1972                       5,791
                   1971                        5,846
                   1970                       5,710
                   1969                       5,629
                   1968                       5,680
                   1967                       5,777
                   1966                       5,517
                   1965                       5,463
    
    This production originated from fewer, but larger producers.  Production
    is being concentrated on larger production units and also in specific geo-
    graphic areas.  In most instances,  new production areas have arisen in
    the South and South Central areas necessitating long distance movement of
    eggs from surplus  producing areas to major metropolitan centers.
                                    X-15
    

    -------
    The production of turkeys in 1972 set an all time record of 2, 424 million
    pounds live weight.  This was in increase of 160, 000, 000 pounds and
    represented the greatest production since 1967.
    
    
                                Pounds Produced       Pounds-Ready
              Year                 Live Weight         to Cook Weight
                                            million pounds
              1972                 2,424                  1,935
              1971                 2,264                  1,809
              1970        .         2,203                  1,757
              1969                 2,027                  1,621
              1968                 2,028                  1,622
              1967                 2,354                  1,883
              1966                 2,107                  1,685           '
              1965                 1,901                  1,521
    Of the total supply of ready-to-cook turkeys over half was sold as cut-up
    or further processed meat.  In 1972 there were about 300 million pounds
    of ready-to-cook turkey cut-up, up 51 percent from the previous year.
    In addition, 639 million pounds were processed beyond the cut-up stage,
    up 14 percent.  Cut-up birds accounted for 17 percent of the total turkey
    certified in Federally-inspected plants and further processed 36 percent.
    
    The production of turkeys  in 1972 set  an all time  record of 2, 424 million
    pounds live weight.  This was an increase of 160, 000, 000 pounds and
    represented the greatest production since 1967.
    
    Milk production is regulated by the U.S.D.A. price support  programs to
    ensure an adequate supply of milk for domestic consumption. Production
    of milk in 1972 equalled 120, 468  million pounds,  an increase of about
    4. 0 billion pounds since 1969 (Table X-3).
    
    The production of milk is being concentrated on an ever - decreasing
    number of farms with fewer dairy cows.  Increased production per cow
    and per farm has offset declines  in the number of cows and farms,  re-
    sulting in a relatively stable supply of milk.  These trends are expected
    to continue in the near future.
                                    X-16
    

    -------
    Table X-3.   Total supply and utilization of milk,  1965 to 1972,  U.S.
    Utilization
    Year
    1965
    1966
    1967
    1968
    1969
    1970
    1971
    1972
    Total
    Supply
    124, 339
    121,283
    120, 109
    117,421
    116,402
    117,493
    118,725
    120,468
    Manufactured
    Products
    Fluid
    Products
    	 million pounds
    61,768 55,400
    57, 900
    59,770
    59,230
    58, 315
    59,992
    61,492
    62,837
    55,400
    54, 000
    53,700
    52, 800
    52, 000
    51,800
    52, 300
    On
    Farm
    5,974
    5, 472
    5, 164
    4, 662
    4, 315
    4, 002
    3, 743
    3, 547
    Total!/
    124,339
    121,283
    120, 109
    117,421
    116, 402
    117,493
    118,725
    120,468
    —-  Total may not equal sums  doe to residuals.  Residuals includes minor
       miscellaneous uses and any inaccuracies in  production and utilization
       estimates.
    Source:  Milk, Production, Disposition and Income,  U. S.D.A., S. R.S. ,
             April,  1973.
             Milk, U.S.D. A.,  S.R.S. , January, 1973.
                                    X-17
    

    -------
       PART XI:   ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS METHODOLOGY
    Responses to changes in factor and product prices by the farm firm
    often are not satisfactorily explained by ordinary economic analysis.
    Current evidence  strongly suggests that larger  farms are financially
    better  off than  small farms and that the break-even point is ever in-
    creasing and may be as high as $40, 000 gross sales.  Yet this per-
    sistence of large numbers of small farms continues in face of cost
    inferences to the contrary drawn from ordinary theoretical and
    accounting analysis.
    
    It should be noted that  significant shifts have and  are  occurring in
    American  agriculture. Farm numbers have decreased  from 4.0
    million in  I960 to 2.9 million in 1971.  While number of farms de-
    clined  by 1.0 million during the past  decade,  cash receipts from farming
    increased  from $34.9 billion to $56.2 million.  Average annual cash
    receipts per farm increased from $8, 800 to $19, 500 during the same
    I960 to 1971 period.  These shifts have  resulted from significant structural
    shifts.  Farms with over $40, 000 annual sales have more than doubled in
    number and in  1971  represented 8. 8 percent of all farms compared to
    2.9 percent in  I960.  Cash receipts from these farms in 1971 represented
    59 percent of all cash receipts from farming compared  to only 33 percent
    in I960.  Cash receipts from farms with less than $10,  000 annual sales
    fell from twenty percent of the total in I960 to 11 percent  in 1971.
    
    While in 1971,  just  over one-third of the farms, Classes I,  II and III,
    produced about 90 percent of the  cash receipts from farming (compared
    to 73 percent in 1960), there still remained 1. 9 million farms (out of a
    total of 2.9 million) with annual sales of under  $10,000  which produced
    only 11 percent of cash receipts. !_/
    
    Explanations for the continuation of small farm units  generally fall  into
    fixed asset theory and the concept of the farm as  a goods and  services
    firm.  Fixed-asset  theory posits that in the short  run the  firm will  con-
    tinue production so  long as revenue covers  variable costs.  In the case
    of farm firms,  certain items such as the farmer's labor and management
    resources may be the length of the  farmer's life.  Hence, the farmer
    may view the salvage value (shadow price) of his  labor  at  or near zero
       Farm Income Situation, ERS,  USDA, FIS-220,  July,  1972,  Washington,
       D. C.
                                     XI-1
    

    -------
    since he may be unwilling or doesn't consider that he has any other occupa-
    tional opportunity and considers his labor to be fixed.   When the farmer
    decides that he does have other occupational opportunities,  he then con-
    siders his  labor to be variable and concludes that revenues no longer
    cover variable costs  and that his financial well being will be enhanced
    by seeking other  employment.
    
    The  goods  and  services  concept perceives the farm as producing off-
    farm services  such as custom work and off-farm jobs as well as goods
    production with durable  fixed resources.  Custom work would include both
    the hiring and the selling of equipment time or an off-farm job.  The
    effect of these  services  is to either raise  revenues, cover variable
    costs or both.
    
    Evidence of the importance of the service concept is  shown in Table
    XI-1.  Off-farm income in 1971 exceeded realized net farm income
    for 65  percent  of the  farms.  It  should also be noted that total income
    per farm operation for operators with farm sales of less than $2, 500
    exceeded Classes  IV and V and  nearly equaled Class III total income.
    Class III farms are those with $10, 000 to $20, 000 annual farm  sales.
    
    The  significance  of the Class VI farm (under $2,500 annual farm sales)
    should be highlighted since it represents a "rural residence" category
    that  will most likely view the value of labor and management resources
    at or near  zero and possibly other fixed assets since the farming activity
    is more of a leisure time activity.  A similar situation may also exist
    for Class IV and  V farms,  but probably to a lesser degree.
    
    Although extensive data  on profits  in farming are  not available, as op-
    posed to sectors  •where  corporations are the dominate business firm,
    sufficient data  are known to state that the book rate of return on in-
    vested capital is  very low--pa rticularly if operator and family labor is
    valued at hired labor wage rates.  Typical midwest cornbelt farms
    have an  ROI in the magnitude of 5.0 percent.  Excluding operator  and
    family labor as a cost,  raises the ROI to  7.0 to 8.0 percent.  This com-
    pares to approximately  10 percent for other segments of the U.S.
    economy. _'
    
    This brief background is given to illustrate the difficulties in formu-
    lating an ordinary quantitative economic analysis of plant shutdown and
    financial impacts. In summary, ordinary economic and accounting analysis
    does not adequately explain farm firm responses to factor and  product
    _L' Farris,  Donald E. and James I. Mallett, Return on Investment in
       Agriculture Compared with Other Business in the U.S. ,  Texas Agri.
       Ext. Ser., MP-1035, June,  1972, College Station, Texas.
                                  XI-2
    

    -------
                  Table  XI-1. Net farm and off-farm income per farm operator by farm size, 1960-1971
    
    Year Income
    
    
    I960 Net farm income
    Off farm income
    Total
    No. of farms
    1965 Net farm income
    Off -farm income
    Total
    No. of farms
    £5 1971 Net farm income
    w Off farm income
    Total
    No. of fa rms
    I
    $40,000
    and
    over
    
    
    $19.0
    2.2
    $21.2
    (113)
    $25.7
    4.4
    $30, 1
    (163)
    $27,3
    6.4
    $33.7
    (253)
    II
    $26,000
    to
    $39,999
    
    
    $ 8.7
    1.7
    $10.4
    (227)
    $ 9.9
    2. 5
    $12.4
    (282)
    $ 9.7
    3.8
    $13.5
    (365)
    III
    $10,000
    to
    $19,999
    
    
    $ 5.4
    1.3
    $ 6.7
    (497)
    $ 6.2
    2. 3
    $ 8.5
    (466)
    $ 6.0
    3.7
    $ 9.7
    (392)
    IV
    $5,000
    to
    $9,999
    
    -------
    price changes.  Further, the limited rationale that does exist for
    explaining these responses is difficult to empirically employ, due
    to the lack of data on how individual producers value or  categorize
    their resources,  i.e., capital,  labor and management.  This should
    be qualified by  stating that the large  agricultural firms, that is with
    sales above $40,000, probably will value their resources more nearly
    at market values  as  do ordinary industrial businesses.
    
    In addition to the  persistence of small and apparent uneconomic farms,
    American agriculture over the years has demonstrated a remarkable
    ability  to expand  production  as required and a remarkable  inability
    to contract production when  no longer needed.
    
    All of the above noted factors plus the limitations of time placed  on
    this study lead  to the conclusion that a quantitative analysis of the key
    impact effects  - price and production -  would not be  feasible.  In fact,
    it is questionable where a rigorous price and closure analysis would be
    warranted over a qualitative analysis in terms of precision of results.
                             A.  Price Effects
    At the outset, it should be recognized that price and production effects
    are intertwined with one  effect having an impact upon the other.  Solu-
    tions  require knowledge of demand growth, price elasticities,  supply
    elasticities,  markets, cost structure and industry structure as well
    as a host of other endogenous  and exogenous factors. In view of the
    complexity and  diversity of factors involved in determining price effects,
    a quantitative approach is not  feasible.  Hence, the price effects analysis
    will be based on fundamental demand and supply theory.
    
    Salient features previously developed and the price  analysis are  as
    follows:
    
           1.  Demand for beef is increasing rapidly although some leveling off
               is expected while the demand for pork is shifting with the popu-
               lation growth rate  and the  demand for milk is expected  to re-
               main constant or increase very slightly.
    
           2.  Price elasticity for these products is inelastic.
    
           3.  Feedlots tend to be primary producers, thus have little  oppor-
               tunity to pass prices backwards.
                                    XI-4
    

    -------
           4. The cattle and swine sectors are composed of many independent
              producers and price takers,  whereas the dairy sector,  although
              many in number possess strong bargaining power through an
              institutional structure creating a few large milk marketing
              cooperatives.
    
           5. Significant technological and  structural shifts  in feedlots are
              occurring.
    
           6. Large numbers of small producers continue to exist although
              ordinary analysis does not explain their persistence.   Their
              presence is partially explained by a combination of fixed assets
              theory and goods and service farm concept (significant  off-farm
              income exists  for small farm operations).
    
           7. Little  salvage  value  for feedlots assets per se.
    
           8. Supplies are extremely inelastic in the short run.
    
    
                           B.  Financial Effects
    Comprehensive financial data  for farm firms and enterprises are not
    widely available.  Further,  as pointed out earlier in this  chapter,  it
    appears that ordinary financial analysis does not explain many farm
    operator decisions.  To provide some insight into the financial impacts
    an after-tax return on investment valued at current market value before
    and after pollution control and before and after cash earnings based on
    model budgets will be computed.  The latter measure is probably a more
    useful financial measure, since for the family farm, it excludes an
    allowance for family labor and management, which is quite difficult
    to value.
    
    Additional factors which also  reduce the usefulness of  financial measures
    include:
    
          -Many farmers do not have cost accounting systems and do not
           know these costs.  (It is realized that some farmers have
           highly sophisticated accounting systems).
    
           -Many,  if not a majority of farmers determine costs of production by
           measuring out-of-pocket costs.  In producing milk, for example,
           out-of-pocket costs would include purchased feed,  medications,
           sanitation supplies and perhaps taxes and insurance.  Other costs such
           as farm grown feed, depreciation, labor and equipment used such
                                     XI-5
    

    -------
           as tractors may not be included as costs since they involve no out-
           of-pocket costs.  As a result of this different concept of determining
           cost, many farmers over-estimate income and, therefore, make
           decisions from a different financial base than do non-farm firms.
    
          -Secondly,  costs  of effluent controls were estimated assuming that
           all investments will be made by purchasing inputs at market  prices,
      *    and that a  typical pollution abatement  system will be adopted.  These
           assumptions were necessary to provide a  common norm for analysis.
           Difficulties in estimating the financial impact of effluent controls on
           farmers is compounded by the different levels  of technologies used
           to accomplish the desired end  results.  Also,  rather than purchase
           effluent disposal systems, many farmers  may build their  own systems
           using existing farm equipment.  Farmers  are  characterized as being
           highly innovative and assumed to have the ability to modify present
           management systems to meet effluent guidelines at minimal costs.
    
    Capital availability will be commented upon,  based on the equity position
    of agriculture  and past history of credit availability.
                          C.   Production Effects
    The effect of imposition of pollution control standards on production will
    be qualitatively analyzed based upon key factors influencing the feedlot
    industry. Rather than make numerical estimates of production effects and
    closures, the magnitude and direction of impacts will be  suggested. As will be
    pointed out in the subsequent impact analysis, the primary production impacts
    are expected to be in the form of structural shifts rather than pollution control
    induced  production changes in the aggregate.
                                    XI-6
    

    -------
     The key factors in which the production impact implications were made
     a re as follows :
    
           -limited knowledge of farmers relative  to actual costs of production
           -production may be a part of a larger integrated farm production
            system.  For example, cash grain production may be a profitable
            alternative for a Midwestern hog producer.
           -the operation is a family tradition and  a way of life
           -there are  few, if any,  opportunity costs for the fixed assets employed
            and for the family labor and management
           -relative changes in cash earnings
           -relationship of investment in pollution  control facilities to primary
            inve stment
           -importance of off-farm income  to small farmers
           -number of producers and  volume by segment size
           -estimated portion of industry with pollution control facilities and
            management  in place
           -already existing and established trends toward significant structural
            shift to larger production units
                             D.   Other Effects
    Other effects  of interest include employment,  community and balance of
    payments.  Employment effects are difficult to assess, since impacted
    farmers have several options:  close the enterprise,  but utilize the land
    resource for cash and production or a pasture type livestock operation;
    liquidate the farm and enter retirement or other occupations; expand
    the feedlot enterprise or simply make the investment and absorb any
    increased costs.  In practice, it is likely that all of the above options
    will be  exercised, but the extent to which each will occur is  not known.
    These factors will be assessed in relation to  employment and community
    effects.
    
    Balance of trade effects were omitted, since  feedlot products are not
    exported in large quantities nor are directly competitive livestock
    products imported in significant quantities.
                                     XI-7
    

    -------
                PART XII:   COST OF POLLUTION CONTROL
    The cost of pollution control was analyzed by first evaluating the state-
    of-art relative to existing pollution controls in  each of eight different
    types of feedlots.   Feedlot segments which had existing effluent controls
    adequate to meet pending standards and tnose which do not need controls
    were dropped from further analysis in Phase II.   Secondly, investment
    and annual operating costs for effluent controls were estimated for feed-
    lot  segments not meeting pending effluent guidelines.
                    A.  State of Art in Pollution Control
      Broiler Industry
    
      All commercial broilers are grown in totally confined production systems with
      no effluent discharge.  Throughout their life cycle, broilers are held in houses
      which protect them from all precipitation and extreme climatic conditions.
      Excretions are dropped on dry litter which effectively absorbs excess moisture.
      Basically broilers are grown in a dry environment.
    
      At frequent intervals litter is  removed from houses  and spread on fields
      in a semi-dry form.   Litter is then turned under as  fertilizer.  No effluent
      problems occur with this system.
    
      Non-commercial broilers usually consist of a  few birds grown "around the
      barnyard." The density of these birds is such  that they do not require
      effluent control.
     Turkey Industry
    
     Turkeys are grown in either totally confined housed systems or on open
     range.  Poults are initially placed in houses and held in  confinement until
     about eight weeks of age.  During this phase of  their life cycle,  turkeys are
     held in a  dry environment protected from precipitation with excretions de-
     posited on dry litter.
    
     At about eight weeks  of age, poults are either placed on  open  range or held
     in confinement.  The  former is the most widely practiced management
     system.   Birds grown out in confinement are held in a relatively dry
     environment with no effluent discharge.
    
     Birds  placed on open range are stocked at a  limited density rate with
     ranges being rotated  from one brood to another.  This management prac-
     tice is used primarily for disease control, but, also effectively prevents
                                        XII-1
    

    -------
    build up of excretions.  With excretions  scattered over a broad area and
    ranges being rotated, we assume that no effluent discharges occur.  There-
    fore, turkey producers are assumed to meet effluent guidelines.
    
    Egg Industry
    
    The majority of all layers are held in confinement housing through their
    life cycle.  The exceptions should be smaller farm flocks which may be
    allowed to roam a barnyard.  If the latter occurs a low density rate  exists with
    no problems resulting from effluent discharges.
    
    Larger flocks are held in confinement  either on floor or in cage systems.
    In both  systems birds are protected from precipitation and held in a rela-
    tively dry environment.  Excretions are either dropped on dry litter or on
    concrete floors.  In both cases manure is removed at frequent intervals
    and spread on fields  in a semi-dry condition and turned under as a source
    of fertilizer, or washed into lagoons.  The  latter  is a relatively new management
    system and producers are assumed to  meet effluent guidelines.
    
    The management systems used in the egg industry effectively  limits effluent
    discharges.  Therefore, we are assuming this industry meets effluent
    guidelines and will not be impacted.
    
    Sheep Industry
    
    Two management systems prevail in the handling  of breeding stock.   In
    the western half of the U.S. , where 80 percent of the breeding stock is
    located, sheep are held on large  ranches which may involve thousands  of
    acres.  In the eastern half of the U. S. , most breeding  stock is in small
    farm flocks. In both cases, sheep are held in pastures with limited density.
    Effluent discharges are widely scattered resulting in limited,  if  any,
    effluent pollution problems.
    
    Little information is  available relative to lamb and sheep feeding in feedlots.
    The following assumptions  were made  after discussions with industry
    personnel and staff members of EPA:
    
          - a  large number of feedlots , feeding  over 1, 000 head per yea r a re
            assumed to presently meet proposed effluent guidelines.
    
          -smaller feedlot operators generally feed in semi-confinement systems
            involving low density lots.  Density  of animals is limited and therefore,
            production units do not need effluent technologies.
                                     XII-Z
    

    -------
     Duck Industry
    
     Currently about 90 percent of the production of ducks is concentrated in five
     states.  Two production systems  presently are in use -- wet and dry lots.
    
     Ducks produced in dry lots have no access to water other than for drinking
     purposes.  Wastes are predominately deposited on litter inside houses  and
     no effluent problems  are evident and these type  of systems are assumed to
     meet effluent guidelines.
    
     Ducks produced in wet lot systems have a dry lot with access to water for
     swimming which is necessary for types of feather development.  These
     operations  are currently expected to meet 1977  standards but require
     additional investments to meet  zero discharge by 1983.   It is believed
     the imposition of effluent controls will impact this type of operation.
     However, due to the lack of necessary data and  the fact thc.t  there is  no
     indication that the imposition of the 1983 standards will have a  significant
     impact on the industry,  impact analysis and further discussion was eliminated.
    
    Fed Cattle Industry
    
    Nearly all fed cattle sold for commercial slaughter are fed in open lot
    confinement.  Exceptions are a  limited number of feeders who feed in
    totally confined systems.
    
    In open lot systems,  cattle are held in high density lots with about ZOO
    square feet  of space per  animal.  Shelter may or may not be provided
    varying by region of the U.S. and size of feedlots. Farmer feeders in the
    midwest normally provide  some shelter while in large feedlots in the west,
    cattle are exposed to all  precipitation.
    
    Feedlots are normally constructed on land with sloping topography. On
    flat  land, lots are mounded to provide some degree of slope.  This practice
    facilitates the disposal of liquid wastes via gravity flow eliminating excess
    liquid waste from animals  or from precipitation.
    
    The technology used in disposing of liquid and dry manure varies  greatly
    from one feedlot to another and by size segment-   Generally, all feedlots
    follow  similar practices  for disposing of solid wastes while considerable
    variation exists in handling liquid runoff.
    
    Normally solid wastes are removed from lots and deposited on fields as
    fertilizer.  Disposal of liquids varies from collection systems using holding
    basin on lagoons to allowing liquid effluent runoff to go directly into streams.
                                    XII-3
    

    -------
    Estimates obtained from EPA indicate that 60-70 percent of all lots with
    1,000 or more head capacity meet effluent guidelines  of zero discharge.
    Only 20-30 percent of all smaller lots have effluent control systems adequate
    to meet proposed standards.
    
    The impact of effluent guidelines will be analyzed assuming the preceding
    percent of feedlots with effluent controls.  All other feedlots are assumed
    to require additional investment costs and, therefore, will be  impacted.
    Hog Industry
    
    Three different types of management systems prevail in hog production:
    (1) open-lot-pasture; (Z) hogs held on concrete with full or partial roofing;
    and (3) full confinement.  It is assumed that the type of management system
    used is correlated with the number of hogs raised annually.  Open  lots
    are assumed to be used extensively by small producers selling 100 to
    300 head annually.  It is also assumed that solid concrete floors with
    roofs are being used by  producers  selling 900 head, and  full confinement
    systems are being used by all larger producers.
    
    In open lot systems  hogs are held on dirt, or  perhaps pasture.  Limited
    shelter is provided with hogs being exposed to precipitation.   Density
    rates vary from 10 to over 100 hogs per acre.  All excretions are normally
    left on the land and  subjected to effluent  runoff.  It is estimated by the EPA,
    that only 5 to 10 percent of all producers with open lot systems meet proposed
    effluent guidelines.
    
    Producers feeding hogs on concrete with pens partially or fully protected,
    use different levels  of technology for manure  disposal than do open lot
    producers.  Solid wastes may either be  scraped from pens or "flushed out"
    with water.   Either  method necessitates removal and spreading on fields or
    use of holding basins or lagoons to  prevent effluent runoff.  Control of liquid
    waste is accomplished through holding basins or lagoons.   Holding basins
    necessitate  disposal of liquids on fields.  It is estimated that 75-80 percent
    of all producers using this management  system meet effluent runoff standards.
    
    Producing hogs in full confinement  systems is a relatively new technology and
    assumed to be a practice primarily employed by larger producers.  These pro-
    duction units are highly visible and are assumed to be  fully regulated, meeting
    effluent runoff standards.
    
    The impact of effluent controls will be analyzed assuming that producers
    marketing 2, 250  or  more  hogs per  year  meet effluent guidelines and will not
    be impacted.   The impacted segment will be smaller producers who have
    inadequate effluent controls.
                                   XII-4
    

    -------
    Dairy Industry
    
    Management systems used in handling dairy cows involves two basic
    technologies:  (1) full confinement during winter months with cows on
    pasture during grazing periods; and (Z) open lot  systems with cows
    held in confinement.  The former practice prevails in the north and north-
    east while the latter prevails in the south, southwest and west-
    
    In using management systems involving full confinement with summer
    pasture, the technology required for manure disposal requires methods
    for removing and spreading solid wastes from barns and controlling effluent
    runoff.   Effluent runoff includes  runoff from holding areas adjacent to barns
    plus water used in cleaning milking equipment and parlors.  It is estimated
    by the EPA that  30 percent of all dairymen with fifty cows or less and 60-70
    percent with 100 to ZOO cows presently meet effluent guidelines.
    
    The technology required for manure disposal for open lots is similar to
    confinement - pasture  system with the  exception of increased requirements
    for controlling effluent discharges.  In open lots, all excretions are exposed
    to precipitation as little protection is provided for animals.  An estimated
    60-70 of all these production units  meet effluent guidelines.
    
    All size segments  of dairy feedlots will be impacted by effluent controls.
    The impact, however,  will be greatest tor  smaller dairymen.
    
    Of the eight industry segments analyzed, it was  the concensus of opinion
    of staff members of EPA that five of these industries already meet  existing
    or proposed effluent  guidelines.  These industries included broilers, turkeys,
    layers,  sheep and  ducks.   The remaining three industry segments,  beef,
    hogs, and dairy, were assumed to  need some degree of additional invest-
    ment to  control effluent runoff.  (Table XII-1)
    
    It was concluded, based upon available data,  that there would be little or
    no impact on the remaining segments,  because  the overwhelming portion of
    these segments either  already have systems capable of controlling effluent
    or production techniques are such that there are no effluent problems.
                                         XII-5
    

    -------
    Table XII- 1.  Estimated current effluent control status, feedlot industry
    
                                          Meet Proposed    Percent Meeting
    _ _ _ _ Effluent Guidelines  Effluent Guidelines
    
    Broilers                                 Yes                 100
    Layers                                   Yes               -~100
    Turkeys                                 Yes               —100
    Sheep                                    Yes               —100
    Ducks                                     */                  *•/
    Beef
      less than 1,000 head                    No                  20-30
      more than 1,000 head                   No
    Swine
      dirt/open lot                            No                   5-10
      concrete /open lot                       No                  75-80
      totally confined                         Yes               ,-. 100
    
    Dairy
      Stanchion barns                         No                  25-35
      Loose barns                            No                  60-70
      Cow yards                              No                  60-70
    •"•
    U Lack of available data necessitated eliminating ducks from impact analysis
                                XII-6
    

    -------
                B.  Incremental Costs of Pollution Control
    Investment costs for meeting pending effluent guidelines were estimated
    for model production units under two assumptions:
    
           1.  Livestock producers at present have the required equipment
               and  land for the removal and disposal of solid manure.  There-
               fore, no additional costs for solid waste removal are required.
    
           2.  Investment costs  required for effluent control consist of
               lagoons —  and/or basin construction to curb runoff and equip-
               ment for the removal and disposal of lagoon liquids.  These
               incremental costs are  assumed to be the only investment
               costs required of livestock producers to meet pending
               effluent guidelines .
    
    These incremental costs were computed for each size segment for beef
    cattle, hog and dairy feedlots.  Cost estimates used were provided by the
    Environmental Protection Agency.  These costs included costs  for con-
    structing lagoons and  equipment for liquid lagoon removal and disposal.
    Size of lagoons required were determined by using the following procedures:
    
               Square feet of lot space per animal was estimated for each
               type of feedlot and size segment.
    
               Precipitation was estimated using  25  year, 24  hour
                rainfall estimates.   These estimates vary by area
               of the U.S.
    
               One  hundred percent runoff was  assumed.
    
               Volume of runoff  was then computed using the following
               equation:
    
               (Sq.  ft. of space/head  x   1   x liquid wt/cubic  ft.  x number  head
                                        12,       ,    -
                x runoff)  J- (liquid wt. /ft  x 27 ft^/yd^)
    
               Lagoon costs were estimated from cost data showing  the
               relationship of construction cost for various size lagoons.
    
               Next,  investment costs for  removal and disposal of lagoon
               liquids were estimated assuming different  levels of  tech-
               nology for va rious size segments.  For example, investment
    _' Use of the word lagoon in this report is considered synonymous with
       the word holding pond.          XII-7
    

    -------
           costs for a small cattle feeder consisted of a pump and liquid
           spreader while larger feeders were assumed to be able to use
           center pivot irrigation systems.   The effluent control  systems
           assumed for each industry segment are summarized in Table
           XII-2.  It is realized that the use of a tank spreader for disposing
           of liquid wastes may not always be possible  due to wet, muddy fields,
           However, the  tank spreader was used for 100  cow dairy operation to
           indicate the options  available to the farmer.  Additional investment
           requirement and its percentage of the original investment for each
           industry segment is shown in Table XII-3.
    
    Annual operating expenses for each type  and size of feedlot were estimated
    using guidelines provided by EPA.   Operating and maintenance costs were
    assumed to equal five and ten percent of investment costs for lagoons  and
    equipment,  respectively.  Depreciation costs were  determined by assuming
    lagoon life of 20 years and equipment life of five years.
    
    Incremental Costs for Beef Cattle Feedlots
    The  incremental costs for meeting effluent guidelines consists of invest-
    ments in lagoons and liquid dispensing systems.  These incremental costs
    varied from $2,050 for a feeder ma rketing 100 head annually to $63,500 for
    feeders marketing 40,000 head (Table XII-4).   Minimum costs for  lagoons of
    $1,550 were assumed for feedlots marketing 500 head or less.  Lagoon costs
    beyond this point increased as size  of feedlots increased but not at a propor-
    tionate rate.   Lagoon costs per head decreased as feedlot capacity increased
    ranging from $15. 50  to $6. 50.
    
    Economies of scale also exist in annual costs for effluent control.  Annual
    costs per head ma rketed va ried from $3. 04 for the smallest feede r to $0.35
    for the largest feeder (Table  XII-4).
    
    Investment in effluent control systems  as a percent of original investment
    varied from 34.0 percent for feeders marketing 100 head to 6.6 percent
    for feeders marketing 40,000 head (Table XII- 5).  This ratio decreased
    for all size segments as feedlot capacity increased.
    
    Cash earnings  for all beef feedlot decreased slightly after investments
    in effluent controls were made (Table XII-6).  Cash earnings before and
    after effluent controls are as follows:
                                 Cash Earnings                            Percent
      Feedlot  Capacity             Before          After         Change      Change
    
               100                $  2,565        $  2,438      -$   127       5.0
               500                  12,080          11,703      -   377       3.1
            1,000                  53,892          53,187      -   705       1.3
            5,000                 175,392         172,672      - 2,720       1.6
           10,000                 395,928         392,053      - 3,875       1.0
           20,000                 848,443         843,393      - 5,050       0.6
                                    XII-8
    

    -------
        Table XII-Z.  Effluent control systems by industry segments
    
                                         Traveling    Tank    Center   Hand Carry
    Segment and Size  Lagoon   Pump       Gun     Spreader   Pivot    Sprinkler
    Beef
    100
    500
    1,000
    5,000
    10,000
    20,000
    Swine
    100
    300
    900
    Dai ry
    25
    50
    100
    200
    500 (Southwest
    & West)
    500 (South)
    1,000 (Southwest
    & West)
    1,000 (South)
    
    X X
    X X
    X X
    X X
    X X
    X X
    
    X X
    X X
    X X
    
    X X
    X X
    X X
    X X
    
    X X
    X X
    
    X X
    X X
                                  XII-9
    

    -------
    Table XII-3. Base feedlot investment and pollution control investment
    Segment and Size
    
    Beef
    100
    500
    1,000
    5,000
    10,000
    20,000
    Swine
    loo
    300
    900
    Dairy
    25
    50
    100
    200
    500 (Southwest
    & West)
    500 (South)
    1,000 (Southwest
    & West)
    1,000 (South)
    Base Feedlot
    Investment
    ($)
    
    6,000
    43,092
    76,780
    427,000
    610,000
    960,000
    
    1,500
    7,500
    25,000
    
    30,000
    48,000
    96,000
    182,000
    
    374,000
    374,000
    
    710,000
    710,000
    Effluent
    Control
    Investment
    ($)
    
    2,050
    4,550
    8, 100
    30,400
    45,500
    63,500
    
    2,050
    3,550
    5, 100
    
    1,200
    1,400
    3,600
    4,200
    
    4,550
    5, 100
    
    4,550
    6,000
    Effluent Control
    Investment as a
    Percent of the
    Base Investment
    (%)
    
    34.2
    10.6
    10.5
    7. 1
    7.4
    6.6
    
    136.7
    47.3
    20.4
    
    4.0
    2.9
    3.7
    2.3
    
    1.2
    1.4
    
    0.6
    0.8
                                    XII-10
    

    -------
        Table XII-4.Investment costs required for effluent control and annual costs,  by size of beef feedlot — ,  U.S.
    Capacity - Number of Head .£/
    
    3/
    Investment Costs —
    La goons _'
    Dispensing System —
    Pump
    Traveling gun
    Center pivot
    Total Investment
    Annual Costs
    Operating and Maintenance —
    La goons
    Equipment
    Depreciation _'
    Lagoons
    Equipment
    Total annual cost
    Estimated percent of production
    units currently meeting present
    effluent guidelines — '
    100
    
    
    1,550
    
    500
    
    
    2,050
    
    
    77
    50
    
    77
    100
    304
    
    
    20-30
    500
    
    
    1,550
    
    
    3,000
    
    4,550
    
    
    77
    300
    
    77
    600
    1,054
    
    
    20-30
    1,000
    
    
    2, 100
    
    
    6,000
    
    8, 100
    
    
    105
    600
    
    105
    1,200
    2,010
    
    
    60-70
    5,000
    
    
    6,400
    
    
    
    24,000
    30,400
    
    
    320
    2,400
    
    320
    4,800
    7,840
    
    
    60-70
    10,000
    
    
    13,500
    
    
    
    - 32,000
    45,500
    
    
    675
    3,200
    
    675
    6,400
    10,950
    
    
    60-70
    20,000
    
    
    26,000
    
    
    
    37, 500
    63,500
    
    
    1,300
    3,750
    
    1,300
    7,500
    13,850
    
    
    60-70
    —' All production units were assumed to be open lots.
    .f*/ Assume turnover rate of "one" for 100 and 500 head lots.  For all other lots a turnover rate of 2. 16 was used.
    ~L' Costs for effluent control.  All production units were assumed to have existing equipment and/or facilities
       for removal of solid wastes.
    

    -------
    X
    I—I
    »—t
    I
    I—>
    ts)
        Footnotes for Table XII-4-  (continued)
    
    
    
        4/
        —  Costs were estimated using the following assumptions:
    
                     lot density equalled one animal per 200  square feet
    
                     runoff of five inches for all lots
    
                     minimal cost of $1, 550 was used for smaller lots
    
                     costs for lots of  1,000 or more head were estimated using data provided by EPA
    
    
        —  Costs for dispensing  effluent  wastes were estimated using data provided by EPA
    
        —  Costs were estimated assuming five and ten percent O&M costs for lagoons and equipment, respectively.
    
        _L'  Lagoon life was estimated at  twenty years.  Life of equipment - five years.
        g /
        —  Percents obtained from EPA.
    

    -------
    Table XII-5. Total investment and annual cost for various sized cattle feedlots, including effluent
                                   controls, Iowa and Arizona,  1971
    Capacity -
    
    Base replacement + investment
    Investment for effluent control
    Total Investment
    Annual Fixed Costs
    Insurance & Taxes
    Interest on Investment
    Mana gement
    Depreciation:
    ^ Lagoon
    K Effluent dispensing equipment
    ,L Facilities and equipment _'
    00 Total Fixed Costs
    Annual Variable Costs
    Stee rs
    Feed
    Labor (hired)
    Vet & Medical
    Taxes (Cattle)
    Interest (Cattle)
    Other
    Operating and maintenance:
    La goon
    Effluent dispensing equipment
    Family labor
    Total Variable Costs
    100
    $ 6,000
    2,050
    8,050
    
    65
    180
    --
    
    77
    100
    324
    746
    
    20, 100
    7,400
    --
    255
    100
    500
    260
    
    77
    50
    864
    29,606
    500
    $ 43,
    4,
    47,
    
    
    1,
    -
    
    
    
    3,
    5,
    
    100,
    37,
    --
    1,
    
    2,
    1,
    
    
    
    1,
    145,
    092
    550
    642
    
    670
    293
    -
    
    77
    600
    078
    718
    
    500
    000
    
    000
    500
    513
    975
    
    77
    300
    463
    328
    1,
    $ 76
    8
    84
    
    1
    2
    
    
    
    1
    5
    10
    
    434
    159
    -
    4
    2
    10
    8
    
    
    
    3
    624
    000
    ,780
    , 100
    ,880
    
    ,296
    ,303
    --
    
    105
    ,200
    ,400
    ,304
    
    , 160
    ,840
    -
    , 104
    , 160
    ,854
    ,640
    
    105
    600
    ,900
    ,363
    Number Head
    5,000
    $ 427,
    30,
    457,
    
    6,
    12,
    11,
    
    
    4,
    25,
    60,
    
    2, 170,
    840,
    58,
    18,
    10,
    54,
    28,
    
    
    2,
    -
    3, 184,
    000
    400
    400
    
    264
    810
    016
    
    320
    800
    596
    806
    
    800
    456
    320
    792
    800
    270
    620
    
    320
    400
    -
    788
    10,000
    $ 610
    45
    655
    
    9
    18
    22
    
    
    6
    36
    93
    
    4,341
    1,680
    87
    37
    21
    108
    44
    
    
    3
    -
    6, 326
    ,000
    , 500
    , 500
    
    ,288
    ,300
    ,032
    
    675
    ,400
    ,504
    , 199
    
    ,600
    ,912
    ,480
    ,584
    ,600
    ,540
    ,496
    
    675
    ,200
    -
    ,087
    20,000
    $ 960
    63
    1,023
    
    14
    28
    32
    
    1
    7
    57
    142
    
    8,683
    3,361
    150
    75
    43
    217
    72
    
    1
    3
    -
    12,608
    ,000
    ,500
    ,500
    
    ,261
    ,800
    ,832
    
    ,300
    ,500
    ,456
    , 149
    
    ,200
    ,824
    ,336
    , 168
    ,200
    ,080
    ,576
    
    ,300
    ,750
    -
    ,434
    

    -------
                                               Table XII-5.    (continued)
    
    Total Costs
    Total Costs Excluding Family Labor
    
    100
    $30,355
    29,491
    
    500
    $151,046
    149,583
    Capacity -
    1,000
    $634,667
    630,767
    Number Head
    5,000
    $3,245,584
    
    10,000
    $6,419,286
    
    20,000
    $12,750,583
     J.'  Depreciation rate for feedlots under 5,000 head capacity was 7 percent, for those with capacity of 5,000 or over,
        6 percent was used.
     Assumptions:
        -Costs were calculated for the 100,  500 and  1,000 head feedlots from various Farm Management Extension Bulletins
         from Iowa  State University
        -Costs were calculated for  the 5,000, 10,000 and 20,000 head feedlots from: "The Arizona Cattle Feeding Industry,"
         Russell Gum and Elmer L. Menzie, Tech.  Bull. 191, Univ. of Arizona, Jan. 1972.
        -All Costs were inflated to  present  1971 cost.
        -Costs were calculated based on a 2. 16 capacity turnover rate for all feedlots except those with 100 and 500
         head capacity which were assumed to feed only once a year.
    
    X
    

    -------
          Table XII-6.  Estimated cashflow for various sized cattle feedlots, including effluent controls.
    Capacity
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
    X
    HH
    1 — 1
    1
    t— '
    Ln
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
    Utilization (Turns per year)
    Annual Output (No. head marketed)
    Sales ±1
    Less Variable Expense:
    Steers
    Feed
    Effluent Controls
    Other
    Less Fixed Expense
    Cash Ea rnings
    Less Depreciation
    Less Interest
    
    P re -Tax Income
    Excluding Family Labor
    Cash Earnings
    Less Depreciation
    Less Interest
    P re -Tax Income
    100
    1.0
    100
    30,745
    
    20, 100
    7,400
    127
    1,479
    65
    1, 574
    501
    683
    
    390
    
    2,438
    501
    683
    1,254
    500
    1.0
    500
    153,725
    
    100, 500
    37,000
    377
    4,938
    670
    10,240
    3,755
    3, 806
    
    2,679
    
    11,703
    3,755
    3,806
    4, 142
    1,000
    2. 16
    2,
    664,
    
    434,
    159,
    
    18,
    1,
    49,
    6,
    13,
    
    29,
    
    53,
    6,
    13,
    33,
    160
    092
    
    160
    840
    705
    804
    296
    287
    705
    157
    
    425
    
    187
    705
    157
    325
    - Number Head
    5,000
    2. 16
    10,
    3,320,
    
    2, 170,
    840,
    2,
    116,
    17,
    172,
    30,
    67,
    
    74,
    
    
    
    
    
    800
    460'
    
    800
    456 -
    720
    532
    280
    672
    716
    080
    
    876
    
    
    
    
    
    10,000
    2. 16
    21,
    6, 640,
    
    4,341,
    1,680,
    3,
    191,
    31,
    392,
    43,
    126,
    
    221,
    
    
    
    
    
    600
    920
    
    600
    912
    875
    160
    320
    053
    579
    840
    
    634
    
    
    
    
    
    20,000
    2. 16
    43,
    13,281,
    
    8,683,
    3,361,
    5,
    341,
    47,
    843,
    66,
    245,
    
    531,
    
    
    
    
    
    200
    840
    
    200
    824
    050
    280
    093
    393
    256
    880
    
    257
    
    
    
    
    
    —  $307. 45 per head = 10 cwt. x . 96  shrink adjustment x . 99 death loss adjustment x $32. 35/cwt.
    

    -------
    Incremental Costs for Hog Feedlots
    
    To meet effluent guidelines, the incremental costs consist of investments
    in lagoons and liquid dispensing equipment.  These incremental costs
    varied from $2,050 for the  operator producing 100 hogs annually to
    $5, 100 for the operator producing 900 hogs annually (Table XII -7).  For
    hog operations producing more than 900 hogs annually, it was assumed
    these operations were meeting existing or pending effluent guidelines,
    therefore they have no incremental costs for effluent controls.  Minimum
    lagoon cost of $  1, 550 were .assumed for the  two smaller  hog operations
    producing 300 hogs 'annually or less.   Lagoon  costs of $2, 100 were
    assumed for the operation producing 900 hogs.
    
    Economies of scale exist in annual costs for effluent control.  Annual
    costs per head produced varied from $3.05 for the smallest hog operation
    to $1.23 for the  operation producing 900 hogs  annually (Table  XII -7).
    
    Investment in effluent control systems,  as a percent of original investment
    varied from 136.7 percent for the operator producing 100 hogs annually to
    20.4 percent for the operator producing 900 hogs (Table  XII -8). For the
    three operations being considered, this  percentage decreased as the size
    of the operation increased.   The  high of 136.7 percent is  explained by
    the fact that the  operator will be  required to have an investment double his
    original investment.
    
    Cash earnings for all three examined hog operations decreased after
    investment for effluent controls were made  (Table XII -9).  Decreases
    in cash earnings for all hog operations were slightly higher than those
    resulting from investment in effluent controls in the  dairy and  fed beef
    industries.  Cash earnings  for hog operations, before and after effluent
    controls are as  follows:
    
    Number of Hogs             Cash Earnings                             Percent
      Marketed	              Before           After         Change      Change
    
             100                $  1,522         $ 1,395       -$127         8.3
             300                  3,334           3,057       -  227         6.8
             900                  7,171            6,766       -  405         5.6
           2,250                 14,018          14,018           0
           7,500                 43,999          43,999           0
                                       XII-16
    

    -------
      Table XII-7 .Investment costs required for effluent controls and annual costs,  by number of hogs marketed annually—'
                                                                                                                     I/
    
    
    Investment Costs —
    Lagoons — '
    4/
    Dispensing System —
    Pump
    Tank Spreader
    Traveling Gun
    Total Investment
    Annual Costs
    Operating and Maintenance —
    Lagoons
    Equipment
    Depreciation _'
    Lagoons
    Equipment
    Total annual costs
    Estimated percent of operations
    currently meeting present ef-
    fluent guidelines —
    
    100
    
    1,550
    
    
    500
    
    
    2,050
    
    
    77
    50
    
    77
    100
    304
    
    
    5-10
    Numbe r
    300
    
    1,550
    
    
    
    2,000
    
    3,550
    
    
    77
    200
    
    77
    400
    754
    
    
    5-10
    of Hogs Marketed
    900
    
    2, 100
    
    
    
    
    3,000
    5, 100
    
    
    105
    300
    
    105
    600
    1, 110
    
    
    75-80
    Annually
    2,250 7,500
    
    
    These operations are assumed
    to meet existing and pending
    effluent guidelines.
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
    100 100
    — ' All enternrises •were as sumed to be farrow-to-finish ho a one rations . Thosp mop. raHnns ma rlrpHno inn anrl ^nn
       hogs annually were assumed to be open dirt lots,  those with 900 hog marketings were assumed to be concrete
       lots, partially or fully roofed, those marketing 2,250 and 7,500 hogs annually were assumed to be  confinement
       operations.
    _' Costs for effluent control.  All production units were assumed to have existing equipment and/or facilities
       for removal of solid wastes.
    

    -------
     Footnotes for Table XII-7.(continued)
    
    
     ~  Costs were estimated using the following assumptions:
                 lagoon  requirement equalled 150 cubic feet per hog
                 minimal costs of $1,550 were used for smaller operations
                 cost for the  900 marketing operation was estimated using data provided by EPA
     4/
     —  Costs for dispersing  effluent wastes were estimated using data provided by EPA
     —  Costs were estimated assuming five and ten percent O&M costs for lagoons and equipment respectively.
     —  Lagoon life was  estimated at twenty years.  Life of equipment was estimated at five years.
     —  Percentages obtained from EPA.
    X
    *—I
    h"'
    I
    h—
    00
    

    -------
           Table XII-8.  Total investment and annual cost in producing hogs (farrow to finisn operation),
                                           including effluent controls
    X
    
    Replacement investment for
    facilities &c equipment
    Investment for effluent controls
    Investment costs
    Annual fixed cost
    Insurance fk Taxes
    Interest on investment
    Depreciation:
    Lagoon
    Effluent dispensing equipment
    Facilities and equipment
    Total fixed cost
    Annual variable cost
    Feed
    Veterinary
    Utilities
    Marketing
    Interest on Breeding Stock
    Operating and Maintenance:
    Lagoon
    Effluent dispensing equipment
    Labor (hired)
    Labor family (includes mgt. )
    Total variable cost
    Total Costs
    Total Cost Excluding Family Labor
    
    100
    
    1,500
    2,050
    3,550
    
    55
    45
    
    77
    100
    150
    427
    
    2,300
    100
    25
    150
    23
    
    77
    50
    -
    972
    3,697
    4,124
    3,152
    
    300
    
    7,500
    3,550
    11,050
    
    165
    225
    
    77
    400
    750
    1,617
    
    8, 115
    300
    90
    450
    69
    
    77
    200
    -
    2,916
    12,217
    13,834
    10,918
    Number of Hogs
    900
    
    25,000
    5,100
    30,100
    
    495
    750
    
    105
    600
    2,500
    4,450
    
    24,245
    900
    900
    1,350
    207
    
    105
    300
    2, 300
    5,346
    35,653
    40,103
    34,757
    Marketed
    2,250
    
    84,000
    I/
    84,000
    
    1,800
    2,5-20
    
    -
    -
    8,400
    12,720
    
    63,450
    2,250
    3, 800
    3,375
    525
    
    -
    -
    4,700
    4,632
    82,732
    94,452
    89,820
    Annually
    7,500
    
    186,500
    I/
    186,500
    
    5,970
    5,590
    
    -
    -
    18,650
    30,210
    
    210,375
    11,250
    14,500
    11,250
    1,725
    
    -
    -
    14,000
    15,440
    278,540
    308,750
    293, 310
                                                                                         continued--
    

    -------
                                               Table  XII-8.   (continued)
    X
    hH
    t-H
    I
    to
    O
          — These operations are assumed to meet existing and pending effluent guidelines.
    
          Assumptions:
             - Assume a sow farrows twice a year with an average of 1 5 pigs per year.
             - Small operations (5-8  sows) have  little investment for  swine production, existing facilities are used by
               many of these enterprises.
             - Assume 450 pounds of feed will produce 100  pounds of market hogs.  Small operations reduce feed cost
               by using more pasture.  Hogs will be marketed at 225 pounds.
             - Marketing cost includes trucking or transportation and commissions.
    

    -------
    Table  XII-9. Estimated cash flow for various  sized hog operations, Including effluent controls
    
    
    Annual output (cwtproduced) —
    Sale si/
    Less variable expenses
    Feed
    Effluent controls!/
    Other I/
    Less fixed expenses
    Cash Earnings
    Less depreciation
    Less interest
    Pre-tax income
    Excluding family labor
    Cash earnings
    Less depreciation
    Less interest
    Pre-tax income
    
    100
    225.0
    $4,152
    
    2,300
    127
    1,247
    55
    423
    327
    68
    28
    
    1,395
    327
    68
    1,000
    
    300
    675. 0
    $12,454
    
    8, 115
    277
    3,756
    165
    141
    1,227
    294
    -1,380
    
    3,057
    1,227
    294
    1,536
    Number of I
    900
    2,025. 0
    $37,361
    
    24,245
    405
    10,796
    495
    1,420
    3,205
    957
    -2,742
    
    6,766
    3,205
    957
    2,60*
    logs
    2,250
    5,062. 5
    $93,393
    
    63,450
    18,757
    1,800
    9,386
    8,400
    3,045
    -2,059
    
    14,018
    8,400
    3,045
    2,573
    
    7,500
    16,875.0
    $311,344
    
    210,375
    66,440
    5,970
    28,559
    18,650
    7,315
    2,594
    
    43,999
    18,650
    7,315
    18,034
    ]J Price of $18.45/cwt.  was used.
    ^JAssume hogs are sold weighing 225 pounds.
    3/Hog operations handling greater than 1,000 head are assumed to meet existing or pending effluent guidelines.
    ^/Includes a charge for family labor.
    

    -------
    Incremental Costs for Dairy Feedlots
    
    Incremental costs for effluent control for dairymen included investment
    costs for lagoons and various dispensing systems.  Total incremental
    costs - lagoons and dispensing systems - varied from $1,200  for a
    25 cow herd to $6,000 for a 1,000 cow herd located in the South (Table
    XII - 10.Minimum costs for lagoons of $1,000 were assumed with costs
    increasing as  herd sizes and  lagoon requirements increased.
    
    Total investments per cow in. effluent control decreased as size of herds
    increased.  Investment costs per cow varied from $44 for 25  cow herds
    to $4.85 per cow for 1,000 cow herds located in the  southwest and/or
    west (Table  XII  - 10).
    
    Investment in  effluent control systems represents an insignificant portion
    of total investment in dairy operations.  A $1,200 investment  for a 25
    cow herd represents a 4. 0 percent increase in investment.  A $6,000 in-
    vestment for a 1,000 cow herd in the south represent less than a one percent
    increase in  investment (Table XII-11.)
    
    Cash earnings for all sizes decreased slightly (Table XII - 12). Decreases
    in cash earnings averaged about 1. 5 percent for small dairymen and less
    than one percent for large dairymen.
    
                                 Cash Earnings                       Percent
    Size of Herd           Before            After        Change     Change
    
         25               $  4,503          $ 4,433         _$70         1.5
         50                  5,643            5,563         . go         1.4
       100                 13,883           13,603         _280         2.0
       200                 22,983           22,663         -320         1.4
       500                 52,684           52,307         -377         0.7
      1,000               103,900          103,523         -377         0.4
                                    XII-22
    

    -------
    Table XH-lOInvestment costs required for effluent control and annual operating costs, by size of dairy herds,  U.S.
    Number of Dairy Cows _!'
    
    
    
    Investment Costs —
    Lagoons --
    Dispensing Systems
    Pump -1
    Tank Spreader —'
    Traveling Gun,
    Hand Carry Sprinklers
    Total investment costs
    Annual Costs —
    Operating & Maintenance
    Lagoons
    Equipment
    Depreciation
    Lagoons
    Equipment
    Total annual costs
    25
    
    
    
    $1,000
    
    200
    
    A /
    t>/
    1,200
    
    
    50
    20
    
    50
    40
    160
    50
    
    
    
    $1,200
    
    200
    
    
    
    1,400
    
    
    60
    20
    
    60
    40
    180
    100
    
    
    
    $1,600
    
    
    2,000
    
    
    3,600
    
    
    80
    200
    
    80
    400
    760
    200
    
    
    
    $2,000
    
    
    
    
    2,200
    4,200
    
    
    100
    220
    
    100
    440
    860
    500
    Southwest
    & West
    
    $1,550
    
    
    
    3,000
    
    4,550
    
    
    77
    300
    
    77
    600
    1,054
    South
    
    
    $2, 100
    
    
    
    3,000
    
    5, 100
    
    
    105
    300
    
    105
    600
    1, 110
    1,
    Southwest
    & West
    
    $1,550
    
    
    
    3,000
    
    4,550
    
    
    77
    300
    
    77
    600
    1,054
    000
    South
    
    
    $3,000
    
    
    
    3,000
    
    6,000
    
    
    150
    300
    
    150
    600
    1,200
     Estimated percent of production
     units currently meeting present
     effluent guidelines
    30
    30
    60-70
    60-70
    60-70
    60-70    60-70
    60-70
    

    -------
    Footnotes for Table XII-10
    
    —  Management systems  used varied by number of milk cows.
                Herds  of 25 and 50 cows were assumed to be housed in stanchion barns.  Cows are  confined in
                winter and held  on pasture  during grazing periods.
                Herds  of 100 and 200 cows  were assumed to be housed in loose barns during winter and held on
                pasture during grazing periods. Milk parlors we re assumed to be used for milking.
                Herds  of 500 and 1,000 cows  were assumed to be confined throughout the year in open lots.
                Lot density of one cow per  400 square feet.  Milk parlors were assumed to be used for milking.
    —' Costs for effluent control.  All production units were  assumed to have existing equipment and facilities for
       removal of solid wastes.
    _' Cost  estimates obtained from EPA.  Investment costs for lagoons sufficient in size to contain milk house
       liquid wastes and runoff from barnyard holding areas  and open lot yards.  Assumptions used for animal
       density rates, runoff, and water requirements for cleaning milking facilities are as follows:
           (a)  Herds  of 25 and 50 cows
                         Holding area of 200  square feet per  cow
                         Runoff  of six inches  of rainfall
                     -    Two gallons of water per cow required daily for cleaning milking equipment
           (b)  Herds  of 100 and 200 cows
                     -    Holding area of 200  square feet per  cow
                         Runoff  of six inches  of rainfall
                         Four gallons of water required daily per cow for cleaning milking parlor and milking
                         equipment
           (c)  Herds  of 500 and 1,000 cows
                         Lot  density of one  cow per 400 square feet
                         Runoff  of six inches  in the south and two inches in the  southwest and west.
                         Ten gallons of water required daily  per cow to clean milking parlor and milking equipment
    —' Cost of pump and limited pipe to dispense lagoon liquids  on dryland,
    $.' Tank spreader costs range from $1,000 to $3,200 depending on size.
    &./ Costs would vary depending on feet of  sprinkler pipe required.
    U Costs were estimated from data provided by EPA.  The following assumptions were used
                Operating and maintenance  costs equal five percent on lagoon costs and ten percent on equipment
                Depreciation. Lagoon life  of 20 years and equipment life of five years.
    

    -------
    Table XII- 11. Total investment and annual costs for dairy herds by number of cows, including effluent
                                       controls,   1971
    
    
    
    
    
    
    25i/
    
    
    sol/
    
    
    iooi/
    
    Size
    200l/
    
    Investment
    
    
    
    
    
    Buildings (Replacement)
    Equipment (Replacement)
    Effluent Controls
    Cattle
    Total Investment
    9,000
    8,500
    1,200
    12,500
    31,200
    13,000
    10,000
    1,400
    25,000
    49,400
    18,000
    28,000
    3,600
    50,000
    99,600
    32,000
    50,000
    4,200
    100,000
    186,200
    of Herd
    500l/
    Southwest
    & West
    78,000
    46,000
    4,550
    250,000
    378,550
    
    500l/
    South
    
    78,000
    46,000
    5,100
    250,000
    379,100
    
    i.oool/
    Southwest
    & West
    144,000
    66,000
    4,550
    500,000
    714,550
    
    1 , OOOl/
    South
    
    144,000
    66,000
    6,000
    500,000
    716,000
    Annual Fixed Cost
    
    
    
    
    
    X
    i — i
    i
    IN!
    
    
    
    Depreciation
    Buildings
    Equipment
    Cows
    Lagoon
    Effluent dispensing equip.
    Insurance
    Taxes
    Interest (Bldg. Ik Equip.)
    Total Fixed Cost
    
    540
    637
    575
    50
    40
    117
    175
    525
    4, 128
    
    780
    750
    1,150
    60
    40
    157
    230
    690
    3,857
    
    1,080
    2,100
    2,300
    80
    400
    307
    460
    1,380
    7,807
    
    1,920
    3,750
    4,600
    100
    440
    547
    820
    2,460
    14,637
    
    4,680
    3,450
    11, 500
    77
    600
    826
    1,240
    3,720
    26,093
    
    4,680
    3,450
    11,500
    105
    600
    826
    1,240
    3,720
    26,121
    
    8,640
    4,950
    23,000
    77
    600
    1,340
    2,010
    6,300
    46,917
    
    8,640
    4,950
    23,000
    150
    600
    1,340
    2,010
    6,300
    46,990
    Annual Variable Cost
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
    Feed
    Bedding
    Breeding
    Veterinary
    Supplies
    Power -fuel
    Auto & Tractor
    Insurance & Tax
    Milk Hauling
    Miscellaneous
    11,000
    1,000
    250
    450
    250
    200
    175
    50
    1,200
    250
    22,000
    2,000
    500
    900
    500
    400
    350
    iod
    2,400
    500
    44,000
    4,000
    1,000
    1,800
    1,000
    800
    800
    200
    4,800
    1,000
    88,000
    8,000
    2,000
    3,600
    2,000
    1,600
    1,000
    400
    9,600
    2,000
    235,500
    -
    5,000
    9,000
    5,000
    4,000
    4,000
    1,000
    24,500
    5,000
    235,500
    -
    5,000
    9,000
    5,000
    4,000
    4,000
    1,000
    24,500
    5,000
    471,000
    -
    10,000
    18,000
    10,000
    8,000
    8,000
    2,000
    45,000
    10,000
    471,000
    -
    10,000
    18,000
    10,000
    8,000
    8,000
    2,000
    45,000
    10,000
                                                                          continued--
    

    -------
                                                  Table  XII-11 (continued)
    
    
    
    Z5l/ 50l/
    Annual Variable Cost (con't)
    Operating and Maintenance
    Lagoon 50 60
    Effluent dispensing equip- 20 20
    Interest (cattle)
    Labor4/
    Total Variable Cost
    Total Cost
    Total Cost (excludes family
    labor)
    375 750
    6,250 9,750
    21,520 40,230
    25,648 44,087
    
    19,398 37,837
    Size of Herd
    iool/ zooJL/ sool/ soo!/
    Southwest South
    & West
    80 100 77 105
    200 2ZO 300 30-0
    1,500 3,000 7,500 7,500
    10,500 19,750 50,000 50,000
    71,680 141,870 350,377 350,405
    79,487 156,507 376,470 376,526
    
    73,237 150,257 370,220 370,276
    
    1 , OOOl/
    Southwest
    & West
    77
    300
    15,000
    100,000
    697,377
    744,294
    
    738,044
    
    1 , OOOl/
    South
    150
    300
    15,000
    100,000
    697,450
    743,990
    
    737,740
    _ Cows are housed in stanchion barns.
    ^J Cows are housed in loose
    £/ Open lots.
    housing.
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
     _' Includes $6,250 family labor charge.
    X
    I
    ro
    

    -------
        Table XII-12. Estimated cash flow for dairy herds by number of cows, including effluent controls, 1971
    
    
    25i
    
    / so!'
    Size of Herd
    100^7
    200^7
    sool/
    
    50017
    Southwest South
    & West
    Utilization
    Annual Output (100 Ibs)
    Sales
    Milk ($6. 20 /100 Ibs)
    Calves
    Total
    Fixed Expenses
    Variable Expenses:
    Effluent controls
    £< Production Related—
    i
    -J Cash Earnings
    Depreciation
    Interest
    Pre-tax Income
    Excluding Family Labor
    Cash Earnings
    Less Depreciation
    Less Interest
    Pre-tax Income
    100%
    3,000
    
    18,600
    1,020
    19,620
    292
    
    70
    21,075
    
    -1,817
    1,842
    900
    -4,559-
    
    4,433
    1,842
    900
    1,691
    100%
    6,000
    
    37,200
    1,980
    39,180
    387
    
    80
    39,400
    
    -687
    2,780
    1,440
    -4,907
    
    5,563
    2,780
    1,440
    1,343
    100%
    12,000
    
    74,000
    3,900
    78,300
    767
    
    280
    69,900
    
    7,353
    5,960
    2,880
    -1,487
    
    13,603
    5,960
    2,880
    4,763
    100%
    24,000
    
    148,800
    7,800
    156,600
    1,367
    
    320
    138,500
    
    16,413
    10,810
    5,460
    143
    
    22,663
    10,810
    5,460
    6,393
    100%
    60,000
    
    372,000
    19, 500
    291, 500
    2,066
    
    7 ~* -7
    343,000
    
    46,057
    20,307
    11, 220
    14,530
    
    52,307
    20,307
    11,220
    20,780
    100%
    60,000
    
    372,000-
    19, 500
    391, 500
    2,066
    
    405
    343,000
    
    46,029
    20,335
    11,220
    14,474
    
    52,279
    20,335
    1 1 , 2.<,0
    20,724
    
    1 , OOOl7
    Southwest
    & West
    100%
    120,000
    
    744,000
    39,000
    783,000
    3,350
    
    377
    682,000
    
    97,273
    37,567
    21,300
    38,406
    
    103,523
    37,567
    21,300
    44,656
    
    1,000 I/
    South
    
    100%
    120,000
    
    744,000
    39,000
    783,000
    3,350
    
    450
    682,000
    
    97,200
    37,340
    21,300
    38,560
    
    103,450
    37,340
    21,300
    44,810
    _' Cows are housed in stanchion barns.
    _' Cows are housed in loose housing.
    3/ Open lots.
    ^1 Includes $6,250 family labor charge.
    

    -------
    

    -------
                      PART XIII:   IMPACT ANALYSIS
    Imposition of zero discharge effluent requirements on the feedlot in-
    dustry will likely  cause adjustments within the feedlot industry, but
    as will be discussed below,  these will largely be structural shifts.
    The impact on each of the eight feedlot segments will vary.  As discussed
    in Chapter XII,  five of the eight feedlot segments were eliminated from
    the impact analysis because these  five segments either do not have effluent
    discharge problems  or,  for the most part, currently meet proposed effluent
    guidelines with inplace  control facilities or management practices.  Thus
    imposition of these control standards would not represent an incremental
    impact on these segments.
    
      Those industry segments eliminated from impact analysis included:
    
             1.   Broiler
             2.   Eggs
             3.   Turkey
             4.   Duck
             5.   Sheep
    
      The remaining industry segments, and therefore potentially impacted
      segments from the establishment of effluent control guidelines are:
    
             1.   Be^f
             2.   Swine
             3.   Dairy
    
      Even within these three segments,  some producers currently are  con-
      sidered to either meet  pending effluent guidelines  or do not have effluent
      control problems.   Table XIII-1  shows estimates of the percent of seg-
      ments that  currently do not meet effluent guidelines.  For beef feedlots,
      this percent ranged from 30 to 40 percent for feedlots with capacities
      greater than 1,000 head to 70 to  80 percent for those feedlots with less
      than  1,000  head. For swine,  percentages  ranged  zero for total   con-
      finement operations to  90 to 95 percent for the small open lot hog oper-
      ations.  Dairy operations not meeting pending effluent guidelines ranged
      from 30 to  40 percent for loose house and cow yard systems  to 70 percent
      for the stanchion barn systems.   Thus, the impact of the proposed pollu-
      tion control standards on these segments will be reduced by consideration
      of inplace control facilities and waste management.
                                       XIII- 1
    

    -------
      Table XIII-1.  Estimated percentages  of those feedlots which do not
                      meet pending effluent guidelines
    Segment & Size
    Technology
    Percent Not Meeting
    Proposed Guidelines
    Beef
    100 capacity
    500 "
    1,000 "
    5,000 "
    10,000 "
    20,000 "
    
    Open/dirt lot
    u
    '"
    1 1
    1 1
    "
    
    70-80
    70-80
    30-40
    20-30
    20-30
    < 10
    Swine
         100 marketed
         300    "
         900    '
       2,250    "
       7,500    "
    Open/dirt lot                 90-95
                                  90-95
    Open/concrete/partial shelter 20-25
    Total confinement                0
        "                            0
    
    
    
    
    
    1,
    25 on hand
    50
    100 "
    200 "
    500
    000
    Stall Barn
    Stall Barn
    Free Barn
    Free Barn
    Cow Yard
    Cow Yard
    
    
    
    >)
    f
    }
    65-75
    65-75
    30-40
    
    30-40
    
    Source:  Communications from the Environmental Protection A gency
                                      XIII-2
    

    -------
     The impacts on these three industries are analyzed by industry and by
     size  segment where appropriate.  The impacts considered in this analysis
     include the following:
    
            A.   Price effects
            B.   Financial effects
            C.   Production effects
            D.   Employment effects
            E.   Community  effects
    
    A comprehensive and quantitative impact analysis was concluded to be
    beyond  the scope  of this  study and perhaps technically not feasible due
    to data  limitations.  Consequently the impact analysis was based on a
    qualitative analysis using broader data and general theoretical concepts
    of the economies  of agriculture.  The objective of the analyses was to
    obtain qualitative inferences  regarding the direction and degree of im-
    pacts .
                             A.   Price Effects
    
     Assessing the price effects emanating from mandatory pollution abatement
     standards inevitably involves exploring both long run and short run demand
     and supply considerations that determine the competitive solution or
     market clearing equilibrium price and quantity.
    
     The difficulties associated with estimating long run demand and  supply
     implications  are  such that a quantitative assessment  of the long  run and short run
     equilibrium price and quantity  is beyond the scope of this analysis.
     The alternative that has been selected is to present a qualitative assessment
     of the probable price effects resulting from the imposition of pollution
     abatement standards.   This is  accomplished by discussing, one,  the price
     changes required  to maintain existing profit levels for various segments of
     the industry, two, probable short run price effects and,  three, expected
     long  run price movements.
    
     1.  Required Price Changes
    
     Price increases required to compensate feedlot producers for the additional
     expenses  incurred by mandatory pollution  abatement  standards are expected
     to be relatively small for the three feedlot  industries.  It should be noted,
     however,  that there is  a considerable va riation between  industries and within
     industry segments.  Certain size segments will require  much higher price
    
    
                                      XIII-3
    

    -------
      increases than others.  Table XIII-2 shows the price increases necessary
      to maintain current profit levels.  These estimates are based on the model
      feedlot analysis discussed earlier.  Table XIII-2 shows that the  required
      price increases range from 0.9 cents per hundred weight of fluid milk
      to $1.35 per hundred weight of hogs.
    
      Swine producers show the highest price increase requirement, ranging from
      $1.35 for open dirt operations marketing 100 head per year to $,55 for
      open concrete lots marketing 900 hogs annually.  Beef follows with a
      required price increase ranging from $.30 for the small open lots marketing
      100 cattle per year'to $.03  for the largest feedlot modeled  (20, 000 head
      capacity and marketing 43,200 head annually).  Dairy requires the  smallest
      price increase, i.e., $.01  for cowyarrl operations with 1,000 head capacity
      to $.06  for free barn operations with  a capacity of 100 head.
    
      It must  be remembered that the above price increases are  those  required
      to maintain existing profit levels from a micro economic viewpoint.  Nothing
      is inferred at this point regarding the ability of various industry  segments
      to extract or realize  such price increases even though they may seem small
      and insignificant.  In addition, nothing is inferred in reference to the ultimate
      burden  of such price  increases.
    
      Z.    Short Run Price  Impacts
    
    Short run price  effects  will predominately be determined by the impact
    of the pollution abatement standards on  industry capacity and by the
    ability of  producers to  influence prices  (market power).
    
    Prices will be sensitive to  the time period in which the proposed pollu-
    tion abatement standards are applied.   The immediate  imposition of ef-
    fluent  controls  could result in a  rapid, temporary contraction of industry
    capacity and, hence, increased prices.   However,  it will be  assumed
    throughout this analysis, that effluent controls will be applied gradually
    over the next four years.   This period of adjustment should be adequate
    to reduce this price effect to a  relatively insignificant level.
    
    In general, individual production units within the industry are price takers
    with very limited market power.  In the case of effluent control costs,  this
    condition would be reinforced by the existence of major producers  within
    the industry which currently meet the proposed effluent guidelines.   The
    impacted portion of the industry would most likely be forced to absorb
    much of the pollution control induced expenses in the form of reduced profits.
    It should  be noted, however,  that the current supply/demand situation may
    cause  prices to rise sufficiently high and to maintain that increase sufficiently
       ^ that, in the short  run, these increases may cover pollution control  costs.
                                    XIII-4
    

    -------
    Table XIII-2.   Estimated price  increases to maintain profitability
               levels after imposition of effluent guidelines
    Segment &
    Size
    Technology
    Price
    Increase
    Percent of
    Base Price
    ($/cwt)
    BEEF
    
    
    1,
    5,
    10,
    20,
    100
    500
    000
    000
    000
    000
    Open/dirt lot
    1 1
    1 1
    1 1
    ii
    f i
    $0.
    0.
    0.
    0.
    0.
    0.
    30
    21
    09
    07
    05
    03
    0.
    0.
    0.
    0.
    0.
    0.
    9
    6
    3
    2
    1
    1
    SWINE
    
    
    
    
    100
    300
    900
    
    Open/dirt lot
    1 1
    Open /concrete/
    partial shelter
    1.
    1.
    0.
    
    35
    11
    54
    
    7.
    6.
    2.
    
    3
    0
    9
    
    DAIRY
    
    
    
    
    
    
    1,
    1,
    25
    50
    100
    200
    500 (Southwest & West)
    500 (South)
    000 (Southwest & West)
    000 (South)
    Stall barn
    ii
    Free barn
    M
    Cow Ya rd
    1 1
    ii
    1 1
    o.
    o.
    0.
    o.
    0.
    0.
    0.
    0.
    05
    03
    06
    03
    01
    01
    00
    01
    0.
    0.
    1.
    0.
    0.
    0.
    0.
    0.
    8
    5
    0
    5
    2
    2
    0
    2
                                   XIII-5
    

    -------
    The net effect of pollution control cost absorption or reduced profit levels
    will be reflected in accelerated industry trends such as the annual exodus
    of small, inefficient producers. Pollution controls will, however, only
    accelerate existing trends in the  short run.  The long run equilibrium
    number of firms is not believed to be significantly altered by pollution
    controls.
    
    While this is the general industry situation,  it is expected to vary by
    industry segment.  A brief assessment of expected short  run price im-
    pacts and market power by industry is presented below which tends to
    support the above summary.
    
    Beef producers  in the past have had very little marketing power.  They
    have no marketing cooperatives like dairy producers, and basically are
    in a free market situation. Also, only 30 to 40 percent of the commercial
    feeders (those with 1, 000 head capacity or more) and 70 to 80 percent of
    the farmer feeders (those with capacities of less than 1,000 head) need to
    make pollution control expenditures.  This  means  that of  the cattle fed in
    197Z, only an estimated 50 percent of them were fed on lots that would
    require additional investment in pollution control and therefore price
    inc reases.
    
    Like the beef feedlot operator, hog producrs are price-takers.  Also,
    they do not have  any strong marketing cooperatives by which they can
    influence the hog market.  However, it is estimated that over 75  percent
    of the hogs marketed come from hog operations requiring effluent controls.
    This coupled with the higher  required price  increases  shown in Table XIII-Z,
    tends to  suggest that the  hog  producing segment is one segment of the industry
    that may not be  able to pass on the added costs of effluent  control.
    
    The dairy  producer,  on the other hand, is in the most  favorable position
    in reference to the ability to  pass on the additional costs of effluent controls.
    This is predominately due to the  strong representation  of producers by
    marketing cooperatives which have the ability to negotiate milk prices with
    the milk processors.  The amount of this price increase that may be passed
    on will be  reasonably small as indicated in Table X1II-2 and is  subject to
    bargaining power or relative negotiating strength.  It is estimated that
    between  four and six cents per cwt.  of milk can be passed on to other
    processors.
    
    The secondary price effects of effluent controls,  in the short run, are
    therefore expected to be  insignificant.  It is anticipated that only a very
    small increase  in the  retail price of beef, swine,  or milk will occur as a
    result of pollution controls.  This is primarily attributed to two factors.
                                    XIII-6
    

    -------
    First, not all feedlots will be affected by effluent controls as was indicated
    in Table XIII-1.  Thus,  the price increases are not necessary for all feed-
    lots.  Second, when considering the small units in which the consumer buys
    (pounds and half  gallons),  the amount of price increase  (as indicated in
    Table XIII-2) per consumer unit would be very small.
    
    3.  Long Run Price Effects
    
    While the above section concluded that the short run price effects of
    pollution control are .relatively small when compared  to price effects
    due to other exogenous forces,  there are several long run trends that
    should be discussed.  Some of these trends are expected to completely
    mitigate any adverse pollution control induced effects and other trends
    could accentuate unfavorably industry trends.  The difficulties  associ-
    ated with predicting long run trends are such that the  following discussion
    will present only a selected portion of the salient industry trends in very
    general terms.
    
    The continual exodus  of small inefficient producers,  the increased market
    share supplied by low cost producers,  technology advances in  the area of
    animal health, breeding and feeding environments all have a tendency to
     result in a  greater  supply at a  lower price.  On the other hand, rising farm
    labor costs and higher prices for feed grain have  an  off-setting influence
    The net effect of such forces can not be accurately assessed at the present
    time.
    
     It does appear,  however, that the demand sufficiently strong is likely
     to increase in the future.  This  force, ceteris paribus, will result in
     increased quantities  sold at higher prices.  These factors, i.e., long
     run demand and supply changes,  are not the direct results of  pollution abate-
     ment standards on the feedlot  industry but are rather the effects  of exogenous
     forces.  Relative to the expected influence of these uncertainties or factors,
     the likely long run impacts of  pollution abatement standards are  quite insigni-
     ficant for this particular industry.
    
     In general,  it can be said that the competitive structure of the industry
     is such that the long  run pollution abatement costs even though they are
     quite insignificant can not be absorbed in the long run and as a result will
     be passed  on to other processors  and  quite likely to  the final consumer.
                                   XIII-7
    

    -------
                           B.  Financial Effects
    1.  Profitability
    
    As pointed out in Chapter XI on methodology, ordinary profitability esti-
    mates are not extremely valid measures for much of the U.S.  farming
    sector.  However,  to provide some insights into the impact of pollution
    control on profitability, two measures of profitability are presented be-
    low -- return on invested capital at current value and cash earnings.
    Because of the paucity of industry financial data,  the model livestock
    enterprise budgets developed in Chapters II, III and IV were used as a
    basis for these estimates.  In evaluating these estimates the reader is
    urged to view these estimates as orders of magnitude and directions and
    not as precise estimates.
    
    As shown in  Chapters II, III, and IV, the beef,  hog and dairy industries
    have  varying returns on invested capital based on the model enterprise
    budgets  ranging from less than five percent to well over one hundred and
    twenty percent.  The wide variation of after-tax ROI is primarily due to
    the differing investment requirements.   (Book value of assets, on which  rates
    of return were calculated, were derived by dividing replacement  costs by
    two plus networking capital (current assets less  current liabilities).  The
    average  fixed investment value is  intended  to approximate  invested  capital.)
    For example, many of the small sized industry segments have very little
    investment requirement, thus the  return on investment is very large.  Con-
    versely,  large feedlots have high investment  requirements and a much
    smaller  ROI.  Thus, investment increases will have varying results on the
    profitability  of the  feedlot industry.  _i'
    
    As shown in  Table  XIII-3, the book rate of  return,  after imposition of
    zero  discharge, is reduced, but the change declines moving from the
    less intensive capital operations to the  more  highly capital intensive
    operations.  The largest declines  in ROI  occurred  in the hog industry
    where a  reduction  of nearly eighty points occurred for the  smallest
    model hog operations. This is primarily due to the more than doubling
    of investment requirements for  the operations existence.  Beef exhibited
    declines over seven percent for the  small beef feedlot operations.  As the
    amount of investment increased, the spread between ROI1 s before and
    after the imposition of effluent guidelines decreased and the difference
    between the  ROI's  for the Z0,000 head feedlot was less  than  one percentage
     I/
    —  Wide variations should be expected in observed industry results due to
       the many factors affecting costs -- weather,  feed costs, animal per-
       formance, management skills, etc.
                                    XIII-8
    

    -------
      Table XIII-3.
    Feedlot book rate of return before and after meeting
             effluent guidelines
    After -tax ROI —
    Segment &c Technological
    Size Level
    Before
    Controls
    After
    Controls
    	 percent 	
    BEEF
    100 Open/dirt lot
    500
    1,000 "
    5,000
    10,000 "
    20,000 "
    SWINE
    100 Open/dirt lot
    300 "
    900 Open/concrete/
    partial shelter
    DAIRY
    25 Stall barn
    50
    100 Free barn
    200
    500 (Southwest & west) Cow yard
    500 (South)
    1.000 (Southwest & west) "
    1,000 (South) "
    
    22.
    12.
    27.
    10.
    15.
    19-
    
    121.
    44.
    19-
    
    
    9-
    4.
    8.
    5.
    8.
    8.
    8.
    8.
    
    5
    1
    6
    4
    4
    0
    
    1
    4
    6
    
    
    0
    6
    5
    9
    6
    6
    1
    1
    
    15. 3
    9-0
    25. 3
    9- 2
    14. 3
    18. 2
    
    41. 8
    20. 6
    11. 7
    
    
    7. 7
    3.9
    7. 1
    5. 1
    8. 1
    8. 0
    8. 1
    7. 8
    —  Represents total return to labor and capital.
                                     XIII-9
    

    -------
    point.  Dairy operations indicated the most constant change in ROI.  Declines
    in model dairy operations ranged froml. 3 percent to 0. 3 percentage points.
    This is explained by the high investment requirement for all sized dairy
    operations.
    
    The above  book rate of return analysis, although indicative, has a number
    of weaknesses centered around the size of investment required both before
    and after pollution  control.  Especially for the smaller operations, the
    additional  required investment was  either greater than the  original invest-
    ment or a  substantial portion of it.   This  greatly affects the outcome of the
    ROI; the operations doubling their investment drastically reducing ROI.
    Consequently,  another  me asure -- cash earnings-- was examined.  This
    measure is considered to be more indicative of change and therefore
    impacts.
    
    The change in cash earnings due to  imposition of effluent controls  on the
    feedlot industry  in general will be relatively slight as  shown in Table
    XIII-4.
    
    The greatest percentage  reductions in  cash earnings will occur for hog
    producers  marketing 900 or less hogs  and beef producers  selling 500 or
    less head.   Cash earnings of larger hog,  larger beef producers and
    dairymen will be affected very little, less than 2.0 percent.
    
    It is likely that the  response of smaller beef  and hog producers to
    reductions in cash earnings will not be significant.  These  producers
    normally do not maintain farm budgets and have little  knowledge of
    costs of production and the profitability of there various farm  enter-
    prises. Their primary means  of determining net income is to deduct
    out-of-pocket expenses from  gross  receipts.  Generally, depreciation,
    costs of home grown feeds and costs of equipment are not  considered
    as production expenses.  As a result,  the decline  in earnings would
    be compared to a higher  cash earnings basis  and the financial  impact
    of effluent  controls would be less  than  using the format used to determine
    cash earnings in this  report.
                                XIII-10
    

    -------
    Table XIII-4.
    Feedlot cash earnings before and after meeting
                effluent guidelines
    Cash Earnings
    Segment &
    Size
    BEEF
    100
    500
    1,000
    5,000
    10,000
    20,000
    SWINE
    100
    300
    900
    
    DAIRY
    25
    50
    100
    200
    500 (SW. & West)
    500 {South)
    1,000 (SW & West)
    1,000 (South)
    Technological
    Level
    
    Open/dirt lot
    I 1
    f I
    1 1
    11
    1 1
    
    Open/dirt lot
    1 1
    Open/ concrete/
    partial shelter
    
    Stall barn
    1 1
    Free barn
    r r
    Cow yc. rd
    it
    it
    1 1
    Before
    Controls
    
    $ 2,565
    12,083
    53,892
    175,392
    395,928
    848,443
    
    1,522
    3,334
    7,171
    
    
    4,503
    5,643
    13,883
    22,983
    52,684
    52,684
    103,900
    103,900
    After
    Controls
    
    $ 2,438
    11,703
    53,187
    172,672
    392,053
    843,393
    
    1,395
    3,057
    6,766
    
    
    4,433
    5,563
    13,603
    22,663
    52,307
    52,279
    103,523
    103,450
    Percent
    Change
    
    -4.9
    -3.1
    -1.3
    -1. 5
    -1.0
    -0.6
    
    -8. 3
    -6.8
    -5.6
    
    
    -1.6
    -1.4
    -2.0
    -1.4
    -0.7
    -0. 8
    -0.4
    -0.4
                                   XIII-U
    

    -------
    2    Capital Availability
    
    Agriculture as a whole is  not highly leveraged, with an 80 percent
    equity position in 1972.J/  Although farmers are using increasing
    quantities of debt financing, they typically use equity financing
    insofar as possible.  Thus,  from a debt-equity viewpoint, agriculture
    in the main possesses a good credit rating.  Comprehensive data on
    equity-debt ratios by type of farm and farm size are unavailable.  In
    general, larger farms are more leveraged than smaller farms.£.'
    Also ,  specialized feedlot  operations tend to be more leveraged than
    general crop-livestock farms.   However, it  should be noted that the
    number of farms selling only animals are limited.
    
    Beef, hog, and dairy producers, in the past,  have  relied upon the
    Production Credit A ssociatioa,  Farmers Home Administration,  and
    particularly private financial institutions, or banks and life insurance
    companies for additional capital.  Cash flows  in these operations have
    generally been attractive.  This plus the high equity positions  have
    caused private financial insitutions to be particularly active in
    financing new investments in facilities.  Private institutions have been
    ably complemented by quasi government credit agencies such as the
    Farmers  Home Administration, Federal Mortgage  Corporation and
    the Production Credit As sociations.  The USDA, through its Agricultural
    Stabilization and Conservation Service,  has developed programs aimed
    at preventing or  abating pollution from livestock wastes.   Programs
    help share costs  on such waste  management facilities as lagoons, liquid
    manure storage,  collecting basins ,  diversion  terraces or similar facil-
    ities needed  by farmers for approved wastes management systems.  Thus
    due to the small  siz,e of investment required for effluent controls when
    compared to the  total farm investment and the lack of difficulty in the
    past of farmers obtaining  financing for new facilities, good cash earnings
    and  governmental help programs, capital is  believed to be available for
    financing effluent control facilities.
                          C.   Production Effects
     Fundamental to the impact analysis of effluent control standards on the
     feedlot industry is its effects on production.   These production effects will
     be considered in two ways.   First,  the effects on individual production units
     is analyzed and then the effects on the total production of feedlots  is considered.
        Agricultural Finance Statistics, ERS,  USDA, AFS-1, May, 1973, Washington,
        B.C.
    ^_>  Garlock, Fred L. , Farmers and their Debts, the Role of Debt in the
        Farm Economy, USDA, Agric.  Econ. Report  93,  June, 1966.
    
                                     XIII- 12
    

    -------
    Inferences concerning feedlot impacts due to the imposition of effluent
    controls were developed by making judgments supported by recent
    trends and characteristics of the feedlot industry.   Due to the lack of
    data, estimates derived by quantitative analyses were considered to
    be unfeasible.   Therefore, qualitative analysis was used to indicate the
    impact on the various feedlot segments and sizes.   In the development
    of impact judgments,  several factors were considered; they are as
    follows:
    
          -The number of feedlot operators has been decreasing in recent years.
           This decline'has been predominately noticeable for the smaller
           operations.  Operators of these existing feedlots either quit farm-
           ing by retiring or working off-farm or they  concentrate on other
           farm enterprises.  Estimates of the number of feedlots in 1977
           are shown in Table XIII-5.  These estimate  were derived using
           recent trends as shown in Figures XIII-1 ,2,  3,  and judgments
           concerning the continuation  of these trends.  It should be noted
           that the  seemingly large decline in the number of smaller dairy
           and hog  producers is due, in part, to the elimination of farms with
           less than $2, 500 gross  sales from the  1969  Agricultural Census.
           It is recognized  that many of these small operators still exist,
           however, it was  assumed that due to the small number of animals
           per farm, they would exist in such a sparse density that the
           operators would  not be  required to control effluent runoff.
    
          -The size of additional investment  required to control effluent runoff
           would also be a factor in determining whether or not to continue  the
           feedlot industry.  As was shown in Chapter  XII,  Table XII-3,  the
           additional investment as a percent of the base  feedlot investment was
           highest for all the  smaller sized model feedlots.   Faced with an
           additional investment requirement, nearly as  large or in one case
           larger than the original investment,  the smaller  feedlot operator may
           do one of three things.  He may decide to close the feedlot enterprise _/
           and concentrate  on his farm resources in other f a rrn enterprises or
           leave agriculture efforts elsewhere.  Secondly,  he may keep his
           livestock but locate them such that they exist in sparse densities
           which do not require investment in effluent control facilities.  For
           example, a small beef feeder may relocate  his cattle in fields at
           densities such that runoff into surface waters  does not exist.
       The word enterprise is used to identify one farm activity contracted to
       the farm which is a collection of one or more enterprises.
                                      XIII-13
    

    -------
        Table XIII-5.   Number of feedlots and estimated 1977 number of
             feedlots, without the pollution control requirements
    
    BEEF
    Capacity (Head)
    <1,000
    1,000-1,999
    2,000-3,999
    4,000-7,999
    8,000-15,999
    16,000-31,999
    32, 000 or more
    SWINE
    Number of
    Hogs on Hand
    CIO
    10-24
    25-99
    100-199
    200-499
    500-999
    1,000 or more
    DAIRY
    Number of
    Cows in Herd
    1-19
    20-50
    51-99
    100 or more
    
    
    1967
    199,290
    904
    479
    293
    139
    56
    12
    
    
    1964
    448,942
    186,778
    276,099
    106,449
    54,550
    6,421
    1,132
    
    
    1964
    871,987
    215,155
    37,601
    8,846
    Number of Feedlots
    
    1972
    152,429
    912
    484
    311
    216
    125
    59
    Number of Producers
    
    1969
    89,789-/
    85,306
    187,682
    92,939
    63,014
    11,119
    2,443
    Number of Producers
    
    1969
    247, 267^
    157,309
    38,457
    9,819
    
    1977
    Estimate
    93,000
    1,000
    540
    450
    270
    170
    80
    
    1977
    Estimate
    50,000
    50,000
    92,000
    74,000
    79,000
    24,000
    7,000
    
    1977
    Estimate
    100,000
    90,000
    40,000
    11,500
    —  Some of this reduction since 1964 is explained by the fact that the 1969 Census
       counted only those animals on farms with gross sales of $2, 500 or more.
                                        XIII-14
    

    -------
           Lastly, if faced with additional investment requirement, the
           operator  may choose to make that investment plus additional
           investments to expand his feeding operation to a more desriable
           size.  Estimates  of specific actions are difficult,  if not impossible
           to predict as pointed up in Chapter XI.
    
          -Cash earnings for all model feedlot operations declined with the
           imposition  of effluent controls (Table XIII-4).  However,  the
           amounts of the decline were slight and it was  assumed that reduction
           in cash earnings would not be a major deciding factor in feedlot
           operations  decision to quit feeding.  The majority of the small
           feeders do  not have precise costs for the operation of their feedlot.
           Often the feedlot is used to supplement or complement other farm
           enterprises and allocation of  costs between the various enterprises
           often is not accurate.  Farmers  also do not tend to include full
           capital costs to their farm enterprises and  they often shadow price
           their own labor at less than market value wage  rates.  These  factors
           tend to support .the assumption that most small feedlot operators tend
           to base their decision to continue feedlot operations on a  variety of
           individual preferences and perceptions rather than ordinary costing
           procedures.
    
          -The smaller feedlots tend to be located on family farms in which
           the eedlot is just one of  several farm enterprises.  The larger feed-
           lots often are incorporated and usually represent the primary
           operation enterprise.
    
          -In each industry segment, some  operations  currently meet pending
           effluent guidelines as was shown in Table XIII-1.  The number
           of feedlots  existing due to effluent  controls will vary for feedlot
           sizes according to the degree to  which feedlots in that size segment
           currently meet the pending guidelines.
    
    As previously indicated,  the effluent  control impact must be qualitatively
    assessed using the procedures   outlined in Chapter XI, as it is not possible
    to develop in model feedlots all  the big cost and judgment factors.  The
    factors listed in Tables  XIII-6,  7, 8, represent key considerations used
    in evaluating the segmental impact.   Examination of these factors by
    segments indicate  that the hog industry  is the feedlot segment that will
    be most likely impacted.
    
    It should be noted  that in  the short run - that is immediate  imposition of
    control standards  - that a number of enterprise closures attributed to
    pollution control would be expected,  since producers would be unable to
    pass on  the increased prices due to the  highly inelastic supply curve.
                                     XIII-15
    

    -------
                                   Table XIII-6.   Factors used in beef feedlot impact analysis
    Technology
    
    ^-1,
    1.
    2,
    
    4,
    8,
    16,
    32,
    100
    500
    000
    000-
    000-
    
    000-
    000-
    000-
    
    
    1,
    3,
    
    7,
    15
    31
    000 or
    
    
    999 I/
    999
    21
    999-
    ,999^
    .999^
    more
    Open
    Open
    Open
    Open
    Open
    
    Open
    Open
    Open
    Open
    lot
    lot
    lot
    lot
    lot
    
    lot
    lot
    lot
    lot
    No. of
    feedlot s
    --
    152, 429
    912
    484
    
    311
    216
    125
    59
    % price
    Estimated increase Cash earn- Investment
    % of change in to main- ings change for controls
    % of fed beef feedlot no. tain equal % feed- w/o price as a percent
    total market- by 1977 w/o cash lots change of original
    feedlots ings controls earnings controlled (percent) investment
    --
    98.6
    .6
    .3
    
    .2
    .1
    .08
    .04
    
    38.
    4.
    5.
    
    8.
    12.
    15.
    16.
    •-
    4
    8
    0
    
    1
    1
    6
    0
    --
    -59,429
    +88
    +56
    
    + 139
    +54
    +45
    +21
    0.9 20-30 -4.9 34
    0.6 20-30 -3.1 11
    20-30
    0.3 60-70 -1.3 10
    60-70
    
    0.2 70-80 -1.5 7
    0.2 70-80 -1.0 'i
    0.1 ;> 90 -0.6 7
    >90
    JL' Effluent costs were derived
    _' Effluent costs were derived
    _' Effluent costs were derived
    Z' Effluent costs were derived
    for a 1, 000 head feedlot
    for a 5, 000 head feedlot
    for a 10, 000 head feedlot
    for a 20, 000 head feedlot
       X
    

    -------
                                        Table XIII-7.  Factors used in swine impact analysis
    No. of
    pro-
    Hogs sold
    t
    
    
    
    
    
    
    
    1,
    2,
    7,
    : 10
    10-24
    25-99
    100-199 -
    200-499 -
    
    500-999 -
    
    000 or more
    250
    500
    Technology ducers
    89,
    85,
    187,
    Open/dirt 92,
    lot
    Open/dirt 63,
    lot
    Open/ cone ret el 1 ,
    partial housed
    2,
    Confinement
    C onf inem e nt
    789
    306
    682
    939
    014
    
    119
    
    443
    -
    -
    % of
    total
    pro-
    duc e r s
    16.9
    16. 0
    35.2
    17.5
    11.8
    
    2. 1
    
    0.5
    --
    --
    1977 esti- % price
    mated change increase Cash earn- Investment
    in producer to main- % pro- ings change for control
    % of no. w/o tain ducers w/o price as a percent
    hogs on effluent cash meeting change of original
    hand controls earnings controls (percent)
    0.8 -49
    2.6 -35
    19.0 -95
    23.7 -18
    33.7 +15
    
    13.2 +12
    
    7. 0 +4
    -_
    --
    ,789
    ,306
    ,682
    ,939 7.3 5-10 -8.3
    ,986 6.1 5-10 -6.8
    
    ,881 3.0 75-80 -5.6
    
    ,557
    100
    100
    investment
    --
    --
    --
    136.7
    47. 3
    
    20.4
    
    —
    --
    --
    —' Effluent costs
    —' Effluent costs
    I/ Effluent costs
    were derived for a hog operation marketing 100 head
    were derived for a hog operation marketing 300 head
    were derived for a hog operation marketing 900 head
         8
    

    -------
    Table XIII-8.  Factors used in dairy impact analysis
    1977 esti- % price
    mated change increase
    % of in producer to main-
    No, of total % of no. w/o tain equal
    pro- pro- cows on effluent cash
    Size of Herd Technology ducers ducers hand controls earnings
    1-19 -- 247,267 54.6 15.2 -147,267
    25 Stall barn -- -- -- -- 0.9
    20-50- Stall barn 157,809 34.7 44.9 - 67,309 0.5
    51-99 -- 38,457 8.5 22.6 + 1,543
    100 or more- Free barn 9,819 2.2 17.3 + 1,681 1.0
    200 Free barn -- -- -- -- 0.5 "\
    500 (Southwest Cow Yard -- -- -- -- 0.3
    & West)
    500 (South) Cow Yard -- -- -- -- 0.3
    1, 000 (Southwest Cow Yard -- -- -- -- Q. 1
    & West) ,
    1,000 (South) Cow Yard -- -- -- -- 0.2 _J
    — Effluent costs were dervied for a 50 cow dairy
    — Effluent costs were derived for a 100 cow dairy
    X
    t— i
    1— 4
    1
    00
    Cash earn- Investment
    % pro- ings change for controls
    ducers w/o price as a percent
    meeting change or original
    controls (percent) investment
    
    30 -1.6 4.0
    30 -1.4 2.9
    --
    60-70 -2.0 3.7
    - -1.4 2.3
    -0.7 1.2
    • 60-70 -0.8 1.4
    -0.4 0.6
    -0.4 -.8
    
    
    
    
    

    -------
    However, with an appropriate lead time and in the longer run, the
    expected closures of feedlot enterprises attributed to pollution control
    alone is anticipated to  relatively small since the significant structural
    shifts are expected  to overshadow pollution control impacts.  In the
    case of the beef, expected demand  growth will also likely create a
    favorable price situation.
    
    The following represents our estimates,  of the impact of effluent controls
    on the prospective impacted segments.
    
    Beef
    It is our opinion that most all of the impacted feedlots will be those with
    capacities of less than 1,000 head and that imposition of the effluent con-
    trols will probably increase the shift to feedlots with 1,000 to  1,999 head
    capacity.
    
    In the past ten years, the number of feedlots with less than 1,000 head
    capacity have been steadily declining as can be seen in Figure  XIII-1.
    The imposition of effluent controls, in  our opinion, will accelerate this
    trend.  This acceleration of the reduction of small feedlots is explained
    in part,  by two factors.  First, it is  important to note tnat a large
    percent of the  feedlots with less than 1 , 000 head capacity will need to invest
    in effluent control facilities.   Table XIII-6 indicated 70 to 80 percent of
    feedlots  under 1,000 head were in need of effluent control.
    
    Second,  the investment expressed as a.  percent of the original facility
    investment tends to be reasonably large for the smaller feedlots.  Table
    XII-3 in  Chapter XII,  indicated that this percent was 34. 2, 10. 6 and 10. 5
    for  model operations with 100, 500, aid 1 , 000 head capacitie s,  respectively.
    This tends to suggest that the smaller feedlots will have to make a sub-
    stantial investment for effluent control when compared to their original
    inve stment.
    
    The reduction  of the  number  of feedlots under  1,000 head between 1962
    and  1972 by about 77 , 000 was  encompassed by a decrease in the number
    of cattle marketed of 64 percent of the  total to 38 percent of the total,
    (TabXe XIII-6).' Further reduction by 1977 of another 59,999 operators
    and expansion  of the  lots of over  1,000 head will further reduce the
    percentage of cattle marketed by these lots -to perhaps something in the
    order of 20 percent.   While the remaining producers will face  in relative
    terms,  significant costs  for pollution control,  it is difficult to  conceive
    all  of these operators closing these feedlot operations.  It seems
    likely that with the demand pull  influence  on  prices, some of these
    operators will at least partially offset these increased costs  with favorable
    prices.  Further, with presence  of the fixed asset concept, the producers
    will continue to produce even at what appears to be uneconomic returns.
    
                                       XIII- 19
    

    -------
    225,000 •
    
    200,000 •
    
    175,000 •
    
    150,000 '
    
    125,000 •
    
    100,000
    
       1000
    
        900 •
    500
    400
    300 •
    200
    100
                                        BEEF
      1962
                                   1,000 - 1.999
                                   2,000 - 3,999
                                  1967
    1972
    1977
      Figure XIII-1.  Previous trends and projected trends for the number of
                     cattle feedlots without imposition of effluent controls,
                     by capacity.
    
                                          XIII-20
    

    -------
    Those feedlots with 1,000 to 1,999 head capacities will likely increase
    in number.  This is primarily explained by smaller feeders expanding their
    operations.  When faced with additional investment requirements, some small
    feeders with capacities less  than 1,000 head,  may choose to also expand
    their feedlot facilities.   The reason for this is that these feeders may feel
    that as long as they have to make investments for effluent controls,  they
    may as well spend a little more and expand their feeding operation.  Thus,
    while the imposition of effluent controls will accelerate the exodus of some
    feedlot enterprises it will also accelerate the expansion of other feedlots.
    
    The imposition of effluent controls is  expected to have very little effect
    on the larger feedlots with capacitites of 2,000 head or more.  This is
    assumed because these sized operations have reasonably large investments  in
    facilities and the additional investment required  which was estimated to be
    less than eight percent of the original investment (Table XIII-3),  will be
    accepted as "just another necessary expense".  Also, as indicated in Table
    XIII-1 , less than 30 percent ol these larger feedlots are  estimated to need
    effluent control investments. No doubt some unique topographical situations
    will be found  on large lots  that will require high  control costs that closure
    will occur.
    
    Overall,  a "new supply"  relationship is seen to be emerging.  Although
    pollution controls will  perhaps dampen its shift to the  right ,  the
    associated pollution control costs are  immaterial relative to  the
    economies of scale and technology  creating the new supply relationships.
    
    Swine
    
    As previously indicated,  the swine segment is likely to be impacted
    hardest of all the feedlot segments.  The primary impact of effluent
    control among hog producers will be among the small producers as
    was  the case for beef feedlots.
    
    Recent trends among the smaller producers (those with less than 200 head)
    have indicated that the  number of producers has  steadily and  rapidly been
    declining (Figure XIII-2).  The imposition of effluent controls will likely
    accelerate this  tendency. However, it is felt, the size segments with
    100 to 200 hogs marketed will be impacted  hardest due to effluent controls.
    This is in part explained by the relationship of the required effluent control
    investment to the producers  original facility investment.   As
    shown in  Table  XIII-7,  investment  costs for effluent  controls were  136
    and 47 percent of the original facility  investment for hog feedlots marketing
    100 and 300 head respectively.  This tends to  indicate that th.3se sized
    operations will  have to make a substantial investment, as  compared to their
    original investment,  to curb  effluent runoff.
                                     XIII-21
    

    -------
    **  2
    0  XJ~
    V.  U O
    V  3 O
    ja -o o
                                             HOGS
    280
    
    
    
    
    
    260
    
    
    
    
    
    240
    
    
    
    
    
    220
    
    
    
    
    
    200
    
    
    
    
    
    180
    
    
    
    
    
    160
    
    
    
    
    
    140
    
    
    
    
    
    120
    
    
    
    
    100
    
    
    
    
    
     80
    
    
    
    
     60
    
    
    
    
    
     40
    
    
    
    
    
     20
          64    65   66    67    68    69    70   71    72
    
                                              (Year)
    73    74   75    76   77
         Figure XII1-2.   Recent trends and projected trends for the number of hog producers
    
                        without imposition of effluent controls by number of hogs marketed
    
                        annually per producer.
                                              XIII-22
    

    -------
     Hog producers with less than 100 head on hand will not be as heavily impacted
     for two reasons:  first, these sized operations have shown very significant
     declines even without effluent controls and; second, in many cases, producers
     can relocate their hogs in areas and/or density where effluent controls will
     not be  required.  Further, these operations are believed to be supplemental
     operations that  augment outside income.
    
     The  100 to 200 head category is believed to be impacted greatest since they
     probably will not have the opportunity to seek different management systems
     and thereby avoid investments in polluti n control facilities.  Thus,  rather
     than making the high investment pollution control facilities  relative to
     existing investment, these operators are more likely to cease the produc-
     tion of hogs.—'
    
    Finally, it was estimated that operations over 500 head will not be greatly
    impacted because they have substantial m-place control facilities.  Thus,
    while the imposition of effluent controls on the  hog industry will eliminate
    some producers,  it will also encourage  producers to expand their hog facil-
    ities and become more specialized in hog production,  so that overall pro-
    duction will not be greatly altered by pollution controls.  Also, it should be
    noted that announcement of effluent guidelines in the near future should allow
    producers to make the necessary adjustments.
    The  small dairymen will be the _nost likely impacted segment of the dairy
    industry due to effluent controls.  We estimate that nearly all exits occurring
    will  be from dairies with less than 50 cows.  Operations with  50 to 100 cow
    herds should increase as some of the smaller operations expand their operation
    and  remain in milk production.
    
    In support of these conclusions, it is noted that in recent years, there has
    been a rapid decline in the number of 1 to 19 dairy herds (Figure XIII-3).
    As was stated, both for the small beef and hog operations,  we assume the
    imposition of effluent  controls  on  the dairy producer  will accelerate this
    decline in the smaller operations.  Remaining small  dairies will either
    make the necessary effluent control investment or else they will locate
    their cows such that they do not require effluent control.
    
    As indicated in Figure XIII-3,  the number of dairy operations with herds
    between ZO and 50  cows will probably decline -without the  imposition of
    effluent controls.  However, with effluent controls,  it is  expected that the
    number of dairies  in this  size group  will increase.  This will result, because
    T7  The 200 to 500 herd category may fall into this s.»me situation since they
        too will probably utilize open dirt lot technology.  However, we suspect
        they may likely continue  this type of operation with pollution controls
        marketing a portion of these grains through hogs rather than making
        significant investments in concrete and housing facilities.
    
                                       XIII-2 3
    

    -------
                                                                  DRAFT
      o
      o
      o
      TJ
      O
    1500
    
    
    
    
    1400
    
    
    
    
    1300
    
    
    
    
    1200
    
    
    
    
    1100
    
    
    
    
    1000
    
    
    
    
    
     500
    
    
    
    
     400
    
    
    
    
    
     300
    
    
    
    
    
     200
    
    
    
    
     100
    
    
    
    
      50 -
    
    
    
    
      40
    
    
    
    
      30
    
    
    
    
    
      20
    
    
    
    
      10 -
    
    
    
    
    
        0
                                   DAIRY
                     59
                                      51-99
                                    100 or more
                             64
    69
    77
    Figure XIII-3.  Previous trends and projected trends for the number of
    
                   dairy producers, without imposition of effluent controls,
    
                   by size of herd.
    
    
                                        XIII-24
    

    -------
    of a natural attrition of herds  under 20  cows due to a trend toward Grade A
    milk production and increased use of labor saving technologies by dairymen .
    Both of these factors plus the additional  investment required for effluent
    controls will most likely necessitate the increasing of her-J. size to achieve
    economies  of scale. Thus, effluent  controls will result in a movement of
    smaller dairies either out of the dairy business or else into larger operations,
    with little impact on total production.
    
    
                           D.   Employment  Effects
    
    Basically, employment effects of effluent controls  on the feedlot industry
    can follow two patterns.  First,  those feedlots curtailing feedlot operation
    can concentrate their resources  in other farm enterprises or  as has  been
    the trend recently,  obtain off-farm jobs  to supplement their farm income.
    Second,  those operators leaving  the feedlot industry can retire.  It is assumed
    that virtually no exiting feedlot operators will join  the ranks of the unemployed.
    This is justified in that most of the exiting feedlots will be small feedlots
    in which the feedlot is  a supplemental farm enterprise, thus the operator
    has other employment  opportunities.
    
      One study of the patterns of Connecticut dairy farms exits indicated that half
      of those operators going out of  the dairy business  "transferred-out", con-
      centrating their resources on other  employment alternatives,  while the other
      half "retired-out" and either sold or rented their farm resources. _
      For purposes of this  study,  it is assumed that one-half to two-thirds of the
      producers leaving the feedlot industry will  remain on the farm and  concentrate
      their resources in other farm enterprises.   The remainder, it is assumed,
      will retire.   These estimates are based on  the study  cited above plus con-
      siderations  for the fact that  on  most of the  feedlot operations exiting, the
      feedlot will  represent only a portion of these operators enterprises thus they
      have employment alternatives on the farm.
                       E.   Resultant Community Effects
    
     It is our conclusion that effluent controls will have  little, if any, economic
     impact upon local communities.  Resources used by feeders discontinuing
     feedlot operation will usually be diverted to other farm alternatives.  In
     the case of the exiting operator,  redirecting his resources into other farm
     enterprises,  capital and hired  labor once used  in the feedlot operation will
     most likely be utilized in the alternative enterprise.  Those operators retiring
     I/  Kottke, Marvin W. ,  "Patterns of Dairy Farm Exit and Growth," College
         of Agriculture Experiment Station, University of Connecticut, Storrs,
         Connecticut,  Bulletin 382, August, 1964, Page 8-9-
    
                                         XIII-25
    

    -------
    from farming (or feedlot operation) because of effluent control requirements,
    will often rent or sell their resources such that the resources will, in all
    probability, become part of larger, more efficient operations.  Thus, the
    exodus of feedlot operations,  will generally tend to redistribute community
    resources from the feedlot enterprise to other .agricultural enterprises
    which will cause very little impact of local communities.
                                           XIII-26
    

    -------
                PART XIV:  LIMITS OF THE ANALYSIS
    The foregoing impact analysis was based upon data and information from
    industry sources, from published secondary data sources, and from sub-
    jective judgment.  At various stages, the data utilized are subject to
    error.
    
    The nature and scope of possible errors should be identified and limits
    placed on the analysis accordingly.   The purpose of this final section is
    to present limits of the analysis in terms of accuracy,  range of error,
    critical assumptions and questions remaining to be answered.
    
                        A.  General Accuracy
    Financial information concerned with investments,  operating costs and
    revenues was in general not available for individual producers or operators
    in the feedlot industry.  Consequently, the financial aspects  of the impact
    analysis were, of necessity, based upon synthesized costs and returns for
    "representative" model feedlots within each segment studied.  The ac-
    curacy of the financial data used is difficult to measure, however, it is
    believed that the  data used are representative.   Various checks were made
    to establish the reasonableness of  the data used.
    
    The  requisite data were  developed by DPRA from a  variety of sources
    including published materials from universities and government agencies,
    previous studies  done by DPRA, information obtained from industry
    sources including trade associations, published financial performance
    data sources, and from private individuals knowledgeable  of the industry.
    
    It is noted that in the recent past the livestock and grain commodity markets
    in general have been exceptionally volatile and  record high prices have been
    established.  These prices  directly affect the feedlot industry and the full
    repercussions on the industry are  not yet known.  Therefore, in order to
    best reflect normal  feeding conditions,  DPRA elected to base the  impact
    analysis on  1971  average price  conditions.
    
    Water pollution control costs were provided by EPA (and Hamilton
    Standard).  These data were developed for typical feedlot operations
    within each  industry segment.   It was necessary to adapt these data to
    correspond  with alternative  sized feedlots.  DPRA  adjusted or scaled
    these data as described above to reflect the general type of change re-
    quired,  but  there may be considerable inaccuracy involved.
    
                                   XIV-1
    

    -------
    Another concern involving effluent control costs is that it was assumed
    all investments for effluent controls are made at market prices, and that
    a typical pollution abatement system would be adopted. These assumptions
    were necessary to provide a  common norm for analysis.  Difficulties in
    estimating the financial impact of effluent controls on  farmers is com-
    pounded by the different levels of technologies used on farms and that
    numerous pollution abatement systems may be used to accomplish the
    desired end results.   Also,  rather  than purchase effluent disposal systems
    many farmers may build their own  systems using existing farm  equipment.
    Farmers are  characterized as being highly innovative  and assumed to  have
    the ability to modify  present  management  systems to meet effluent guide-
    lines at minimal costs. This may result in a wide variation in actual
    control costs  for different operators with  the same sized  feedlot.
    
    
                            B.   Range of Error
    All cost  of production and financial data are assumed to reflect model
    production units.  Variations in costs and profitability for individual units
    could result in an error ranging from _+ 20 percent,  particularly for smaller
    units.  Error for larger feedlots is estimated to  range  from + ten percent.
    
    Pollution control costs used were supplied by the Environmental Protection
    Agency and assumed to reflect representative costs  for production units
    throughout the U.S.  However, different technologies for effluent control
    are available  with systems varying throughout the nation.  Pollution costs
    could involve  an error ranging from  + 30 percent for small producers
    with this percent decreasing for larger feedlots.
    
    Even if estimated costs of effluent control  systems involve 30 percent error,
    this error would have little effect on  the conclusions drawn in this report.
    The reason is that investments in pollution abatement system  represent a
    small percent of investments in feedlots,  excepting  the smallest feedlots.
    
                          C.   Critical Assumptions
    In order to complete this analysis of the feedlot industry within the scope
    of study established, a variety of assumptions were required.  Some
    critical assumptions were applicable to all segments studied,  while
    others were  specific to a given subindustry.  The main assumptions
    deserving further comment  are described below.
                                 XIV-2
    

    -------
    Representativeness of Model Feedlots.  It is difficult to represent an
    industry or subindustry with models when there are actually many types
    and sizes of feedlots in  the industry.   In the three subindustries studied,
    the most difficult to represent was  the hog industry.   Variations in manage-
    ment  practices and differences in facilities indicate that it is most  likely
    that no two operations are alike.
    
    The hog model operations were assumed to represent overall  "typical"
    feedlot operations.  This approach  seemed reasonable within the limits
    of this study,  but additional data would be required to simulate the  various
    other operations.
    
    The other feedlot segments are less subject to wide variation  although
    management practices can differ from the assumed conditions.
    
    Model Plant Cost Data.  Cost budgets  were based on published reports
    covering periods ranging from the mid to late sixties. These budgets
    were  then updated to reflect 1971 conditions assuming past relationships,
    as in  cost of inputs,  remained constant.   The resulting model feedlot data
    are believed reasonable and representative, but it remains that the  lack
    of recent data necessitated that synthesis techniques had to be relied upon.
    However, even if the data were available, it is questionable that it  would
    provide more accurate model represntatives.  This is predominately due
    to the fact  that it is our  opinion that economic and accounting analyses do
    not sufficiently explain farmer's  responses.
    
    Prices and Inflation.  Current prices in  the livestock and feed grains markets
    are presently distorted  and not believed  representative of future expectations.
    Prices and costs used in the model feedlot cases are  typically averages for
    1971.  This price data is assumed to better represent the feedlot industry.
    
    Regarding  the impact of inflation on the model plant analyses, it is
    commonly  assumed that both costs  and returns will be proportionately
    affected by inflation such that the impact is offsetting. However, it is
    noted that pollution control costs are increasing relatively faster than
    other segments of the economy.   Thus, one might question the accuracy
    of the estimated  1977 and 1983 waste treatment costs relative to other
    costs  and prices.
    
    Status of Current Effluent Controls. Within the feedlot industry, the status
    of current  effluent  controls varies both with the segment and the sizes of
    operations within that segment.  Estimates of the current status were ob-
    tained from EPA (and Hamilton Standard) and are assumed to  be reflective
    of the feedlot industry.
                                     XIV-3
    

    -------
    Water Pollution Controls.  In assessing the  impacts of the effluent
    control costs  provided,  no allowance was assumed for farmers constructing
    effluent controls themselves.  Also a standard control system was assumed
    for each sized industry  segment, which in actuality will  probably not be the
    case.
    
    Most of these anr1  h.her less critical  assumptions  have been discussed
    previously in  this report.  Such assumptions are based upon best judgments
    given prevailing conditions in the feedlot industry.
                          D.   Questions Remaining
    
    Primarily questions  remaining concern a more precise knowledge of data
    pertaining to feedlots and the effluent controls required.  Some of the key
    additional data needed for a more thorough analysis of the effluent control
    impact would include:
    
           -Accurate estimates of the management systems used by different
             types of feedlots.  Management systems used partially determine
             the level of technology required for effluent control.
    
           -The age of production facilities.  Data needed in order to more
             accurately predict salvage value of assets.
    
           -Percent of feedlots which could construct effluent control  systems
             adjacent to present feedlots.  This site data would facilitate
             analysis of relocations of feedlots and predicting the exodus of
             feedlots.
                                 XIV-4
    

    -------
    APPENDIX III-l
    

    -------
    Appendix III-l.   Number of farms selling market hogs and feeders,
             percent of hogs sold,  by size, twenty leading states, 1969
    and
    Number of
    
    IOWA
    Market Hogs
    Farms
    % farms
    % hogs sold
    Feeder Pigs
    Farms
    % farms
    % pigs sold
    Total Farms
    % farms
    ILLINOIS
    Market HOJJS
    Farms
    % farms
    % hogs sold
    Feeder Pigs
    Farms
    % farms
    % pigs sold
    Total Farms
    % farms
    1-9
    
    
    993
    1.4
    . 1
    
    67
    0.5
    0. 1
    1,060
    1.2
    
    
    1, 147
    3.0
    0. 1
    
    83
    1.0
    0. 1
    1,230
    2.6
    10-49
    
    
    7., 760
    10.9
    1.3
    
    1, 132
    8.3
    1. 1
    8,892
    10.5
    
    
    6,977
    18.2
    2.2
    
    1, 158
    14. 1
    2. 1
    8, 135
    17.5
    50-99
    
    
    11,641
    16.3
    4.8
    
    1,904
    13.9
    4. 1
    13,545
    15.9
    
    
    7, 161
    18.6
    5.7
    
    1,594
    19.5
    6.3
    8,755
    18.8
    100-
    199
    
    
    18,691
    26.3
    15.5
    
    3,423
    25.0
    12.9
    22, 114
    26.0
    
    
    8,654
    22.6
    13.7
    
    2, 168
    26.5
    16.2
    10,822
    23.2
    Hogs Sold
    200-
    499
    
    
    24,912
    35.0
    44.9
    
    5,001
    36,5
    36. 1
    29,913
    35.2
    
    
    9,946
    25.9
    34.7
    
    2, 183
    26.7
    32.4
    12,129
    26. 1
    500-
    999
    
    
    6,250
    8.8
    24.6
    
    1,710
    12.5
    27.0
    7,960
    9.4
    
    
    3,432
    8.9
    25.8
    
    746
    9. 1
    24. 1
    4, 178
    9.0
    1,000+
    
    
    995
    1.4
    8.8
    
    458
    3.3
    18.7
    1,453
    1.8
    
    
    1,048
    2.8
    17.8
    
    251
    3. 1
    18.8
    1,299
    2.8
    Total
    
    
    71,242
    100
    100
    
    13,695
    100
    100
    84,937
    100
    
    
    38,365
    100
    100
    
    8, 183
    100
    100
    46,548
    100
    

    -------
    Appendix III-1 (continued)
    Number of
    
    OHIO
    Market Hogs
    Farms
    % farms
    % hogs sold
    Feeder Pigs
    Farms
    % farms
    % pigs sold
    Total Farms
    % farms
    KANSAS
    Market Hogs
    Farms
    % farms
    % hogs sold
    Feeder Pigs
    Farms
    % farms
    % pigs sold
    Total Farms
    % farms
    1-9
    
    
    1, 123
    5.6
    0.2
    
    87
    1.8
    0. 1
    1,210
    4.9
    
    
    1,085
    7.5
    0.2
    
    87
    1.9
    0. 1
    1, 172
    6. 1
    10-49
    
    
    5,459.
    27. 1
    4.7
    
    1,058
    22.6
    4.2
    6,517
    26.3
    
    
    4,309
    29.8
    5.4
    
    938
    20.2
    3.7
    5,247
    27.5
    50-99
    
    
    4,498
    22.4
    10. 1
    
    1,077
    23.0
    9.2
    5, 575
    22. 5
    
    
    3,239
    22.4
    10.8
    
    1,076
    23. 1
    9.6
    4,315
    22.6
    100-
    199
    
    
    4,243
    21. 1
    18.7
    
    1, 155
    24.7
    19.6
    5,398
    21.8
    
    
    2,938
    20.3
    19.8
    
    1, 177
    25.3
    19.3
    4, 115
    21.5
    Hogs Sold
    200-
    499
    
    
    3,638
    18. 1
    34.9
    
    944
    20.2
    31.7
    4,582
    18.5
    
    
    2,249
    15.6
    33.3
    
    1,059
    22.7
    35.7
    3,308
    17.3
    500-
    999
    
    
    903
    4. 5
    19.5
    
    271
    5.8
    20.2
    1, 174
    4.7
    
    
    478
    3.3
    15.8
    
    240
    5. 1
    18.7
    718
    3.8
    1,000-f
    
    
    244
    1.2
    11.9
    
    89
    1.9
    15.0
    333
    1.3
    
    
    148
    1. 1
    14.7
    
    77
    1.7
    12.9
    225
    1.2
    Total
    
    
    20, 108
    100
    100
    
    4,681
    100
    100
    24,789
    100
    
    
    14,446
    100
    100
    
    4,654
    100
    100
    19, 100
    100
    

    -------
    Appendix III-1 (continued)
    Number of Hogs Sold
    
    1-9
    10-49
    50-99
    100-
    199
    200-
    499
    500-
    999
    1,000+
    Total
    NORTH CAROLINA
    Market Hogs
    Farms
    % farms
    % hogs sold
    Feeder Pigs
    Farms
    % fa rm s
    % pigs sold
    Total Farms
    % farms
    SOUTH DAKOTA
    Market Hogs
    Farms
    % fa rm s
    % hogs sold
    Feeder Pigs
    Farms
    % farms
    % pigs sold
    Total Fa rms
    % fa rm s
    
    2,323
    15.9
    0.7
    
    369
    7. 5
    0.4
    2,692
    13.8
    
    
    613
    3.9
    0. 1
    
    65
    2.2
    0. 1
    678
    3.6
    
    6, 526
    44.7
    10. 1
    
    2,029
    41.3
    8.7
    8,555
    43.8
    
    
    3,495
    22. 1
    4. 5
    
    522
    17.4
    3.3
    4,017
    21.3
    
    2,565
    17.5
    11.6
    
    988
    20. 1
    10. 1
    3, 553
    18.2
    
    
    4,094
    25.8
    13.3
    
    674
    22. 5
    9.0
    4,768
    25.3
    
    1,687
    11.5
    15.0
    
    789
    16. 1
    16. 1
    2,476
    12.7
    
    
    4,374
    27.6
    28.0
    
    848
    28.3
    20. 5
    5,222
    27.8
    
    1,051
    7.2
    20.4
    
    511
    10.4
    23. 1
    1,562
    8.0
    
    
    2,833
    17.9
    37.5
    
    700
    23.3
    37.0
    3,533
    18.8
    
    277
    1. 9
    12.7
    
    136
    2.8
    13.4
    413
    2. 1
    
    
    353
    2.2
    10.9
    
    145
    4.8
    17.2
    498
    2.6
    
    180
    1.3
    29.5
    
    90
    1.8
    28.2
    270
    1.4
    
    
    72
    0.5
    5.7
    
    44
    1.5
    12.9
    116
    0.6
    
    14,609
    100
    100
    
    4, 912
    100
    100
    19,521
    100
    
    
    15,834
    100
    100
    
    2,998
    100
    100
    18,832
    100
    

    -------
                            Appendix III-1.  (continued)
                                          Number of Hogs Sold
                     1-9
    10-49   50-99
            100-
            199
            200-
            499
            500-
            999
            1,000+    Total
    MISSOURI
      Market Hogs
       Farms        1,272
       % farms        4.0
    
       % hogs sold     0. 1
    
      Feeder Pigs
       Farms         158
       % farms        1.5
    
       % pigs sold     0. 1
    
      Total Farms    1,430
       % farms        3. 4
    
    INDIANA
      Market Hogs
       Farms         786
       % farms        3.0
    
       % hogs sold     0. 1
    
      Feeder Pigs
       Farms          46
       % farms        0.8
    
       % pigs sold     0. 1
    
      Total Farms      832
       % farms        2. 6
    7,560   7,003    7,344    6,558   1,452    369
    24.0    22.2     23.3     20.8     4.6     1.1
     4.0
    2, 172
    21. 1
    
     4.2
    
    9,732
    23.3
     2.5
      861
    14.5
    
     2.2
    
    6,007
    18.7
     9.4
    19.5
    2,420   2,833
    23.6    27.6
    10.5
    23.7
    9,423  10,177
    22.5    24.3
     6.5
    1,264
    21.3
    
     6.9
    
    6,442
    20. 1
    14.4
    1,585
    26.7
    
    16.6
    
    7,514
    23.5
    37. 1
    2,081
    20.3
    
    34.0
    
    8,639
    20.7
    5,146   5,178    5,929    6,377
    19.7    19.9     22.8     24.5
    34.0
    1,514
    25.4
    
    31.8
    
    7,891
    24.7
    18.3
      484
     4.7
    
    17.5
    
    1,939
     4.6
    2,074
     7.9
    
    24.2
      499
     8.4
    
    23.8
    
    2,573
     8.0
    11.6
      122
     1.3
    
    10.0
    
     491
     1.2
     633
     2.2
    
    18.3
      171
     2.9
    
    18.6
    
      804
     2.4
    31,558
     100
    
     100
    10,270
     100
    
     100
    
    41,828
     100
    26,063
     100
    
     100
     5,940
     100
    
     100
    
    32,003
     100
    

    -------
    Appendix III-1 (continued)
    Number of
    
    MINNESOTA
    Market Hogs
    Farms
    % farms
    % hogs sold
    Feeder Pigs
    Farms
    % farms
    % pigs sold
    Total Farms
    % farms
    NEBRASKA
    Market Hogs
    Farms
    % farms
    % hogs sold
    Feeder Pigs
    Farms
    % farms
    % pigs sold
    Total Farms
    % farms
    1-9
    
    
    1,582
    5.6
    0.2
    
    169
    1.9
    0. 1
    1,751
    4.8
    
    
    882
    3.6
    0. 1
    
    51
    1.0
    0. 1
    933
    3. 1
    10-49
    
    
    6,832
    24.4
    4.8
    
    1,999
    22.9
    4.3
    8,831
    24. 1
    
    
    5,672
    23.0
    4.2
    
    768
    15.2
    2.6
    6,440
    21.7
    50-99
    
    
    6,677
    23.9
    11.8
    
    1,925
    22. 1
    9.6
    8,602
    23.4
    
    
    5,709
    23. 1
    10.6
    
    1,043
    20.6
    7. 5
    6,752
    22.7
    100-
    199
    
    
    6,764
    24.2
    23.8
    
    2, 195
    25.2
    20.0
    8,959
    24.4
    
    
    6,451
    26. 1
    23.9
    
    1,373
    27.2
    17.7
    7,824
    26.3
    Hogs Sold
    200-
    499
    
    
    5,061
    18. 1
    37.3
    
    1,857
    21.3
    35.2
    6,918
    18.9
    
    
    5,035
    20.4
    40.2
    
    1,388
    27.5
    35. 1
    6,423
    J1.6
    500-
    999
    
    
    901
    3.2
    15.7
    
    469
    5.4
    19.8
    1,370
    3.7
    
    
    806
    3.3
    14.7
    
    318
    6.3
    19.2
    1, 124
    3.8
    1,000+
    
    
    165
    0.6
    6.4
    
    104
    1.2
    11.0
    269
    0.7
    
    
    133
    0.5
    6.3
    
    111
    2.2
    17.8
    244
    0.8
    Total
    
    
    27,982
    100
    100
    
    8,718
    100
    100
    36,700
    100
    
    
    24,688
    100
    100
    
    5,052
    100
    100
    29,740
    100
    

    -------
    Appendix III-1 (continued)
    Number of
    
    TENNESSEE
    Market Hogs
    Farms
    % farms
    % hogs sold
    Feeder Pigs
    Farms
    % farms
    % pigs sold
    Total Farms
    % farms
    ALABAMA
    Market Hogs
    Farms
    % farms
    % hogs sold
    Feeder Pigs
    Farms
    % farms
    % pigs sold
    Total Farms
    % farms
    1-9
    
    
    1,278
    11.5
    0.5
    
    307
    4.8
    0.4
    1,585
    9.0
    
    
    715
    9.0
    0.4
    
    109
    4.7
    0.3
    824
    8.0
    10-49
    
    
    4,432
    39.8
    11.2
    
    2,359
    37.0
    11.8
    6,791
    38.8
    
    
    3,034
    38. 1
    9.1
    
    801
    34.8
    9. 1
    3,835
    37.4
    50-99
    
    
    2,549
    22.9
    17.6
    
    1,741
    27.3
    20.7
    4,290
    24.5
    
    
    1,862
    23.4
    14.5
    
    563
    24.5
    14.2
    2,425
    23.6
    100-
    199
    
    
    1,721
    15.4
    23. 1
    
    1,286
    20.2
    30. 1
    3,007
    17.2
    
    
    1,383
    17.4
    21.2
    
    472
    20.5
    23. 1
    1,855
    18. 1
    Hogs Sold
    200-
    499
    
    
    914
    8.2
    25.9
    
    603
    9.5
    27.9
    1,517
    8.7
    
    
    728
    9.2
    23.9
    
    284
    12.4
    31.8
    1,012
    9.9
    500-
    99
    
    
    178
    1.6
    11.3
    
    73
    1. 1
    7.2
    251
    1.4
    
    
    147
    1.8
    11.4
    
    60
    2.6
    15.3
    207
    2.0
    1,000+
    
    
    68
    0.6
    10.4
    
    8
    0. 1
    1.9
    76
    0.4
    
    
    85
    1. 1
    19.5
    
    13
    0.5
    6.2
    98
    1.0
    Total
    
    
    11, 140
    100
    100
    
    6,377
    100
    100
    17,517
    100
    
    
    7,954
    100
    100
    
    2,302
    100
    100
    10,256
    100
    

    -------
    Appendix III-l (continued)
    Number of
    
    MICHIGAN
    Market Hogs
    Farms
    % farms
    % hogs sold
    Feeder Pigs
    Farms
    % farms
    % pigs sold
    Total farms
    % farms
    SOUTH CAROLINA
    Market Hogs
    Farms
    % farms
    % hogs sold
    Feeder Pigs
    Farms
    % farms
    % pigs sold
    Total Farms
    % farms
    1-9
    
    
    753
    1Z.3
    0.5
    
    76
    3.9
    0.2
    829
    10.3
    
    
    706
    15.0
    0.9
    
    81
    7.6
    0.7
    787
    13.7
    10-49
    
    
    2,223
    36.3
    7.7
    
    545
    28.0
    4.9
    2,768
    34.3
    
    
    2,252
    47.9
    14.2
    
    513
    48.4
    16.3
    2,765
    48.0
    50-99
    
    
    1,241
    20.3
    11.7
    
    438
    22.6
    9.4
    1,679
    20.8
    
    
    814
    17.3
    14.8
    
    224
    21. 1
    17.3
    1,038
    18.0
    100-
    199
    
    
    965
    15.8
    18.2
    
    410
    21. 1
    17.2
    1,375
    17. 1
    
    
    522
    11. 1
    18.5
    
    133
    12.5
    17.9
    655
    11.3
    Hogs Sold
    200-
    499
    
    
    684
    11.2
    28.3
    
    337
    17.4
    30. 1
    1,021
    12.7
    
    
    300
    6.4
    22.8
    
    76
    7.2
    23.8
    376
    6.5
    500-
    999
    
    
    195
    3.2
    17.8
    
    93
    4.8
    18.4
    288
    3.6
    
    
    73
    1.6
    12.9
    
    23
    2.2
    14.2
    96
    1.7
    1,000 +
    
    
    61
    0.9
    15.8
    
    43
    2.2
    19.8
    104
    1.2
    
    
    34
    0.7
    15.9
    
    11
    1.0
    9.8
    45
    0.8
    Total
    
    
    6, 122
    100
    100
    
    1,942
    100
    100
    8,064
    100
    
    
    4,701
    100
    100
    
    1,061
    100
    100
    5,762
    100
    

    -------
                            Appendix III-l (continued)
                     '1-9
                                          Number of Hogs Sold
             10-49   50-99
                    100-
                    199
                    200-
                    499
                    500-
                    999
                   1,000+   Total
    WISCONSIN
     Market Hogs
       Farms
       % farms
    
       % hogs sold
    
     Feeder Pigs
       Farms
       % farms
    
       % pigs  sold
    
     Total Farms
       % farms
    
    GEORGIA
     Market Hogs
       % farms
    
       % hogs sold
    
     Feeder Pigs
       Farms
       % farms
    
       % pigs  sold
    
     Total Farms
       % farms
    1,544
     10.3
    
      0.3
      273
      3.2
    
      0.2
    
    1,817
      7.7
      741
      5.5
    
      0.2
      101
      3.8
    
      0.3
    
      842
      5.3
    4,525   3,199   3,014    2,203
    30.3    21.4    20.2     14.8
     6.6
    2,548
    29.8
    
     6.4
    
    7,073
    30. 1
     6.2
      947
    35.2
    
    10.3
    
    5,088
    31.7
    12.5
    1,967
    23.0
    
    12.2
    
    5, 166
    22.0
    12.5
      703
    26.2
    
    15.3
    
    3,982
    24.8
    23.3
    1,995
    23.3
    
    24. 1
    
    5,009
    21.3
    4,141   3,279   2,723
    31.0    24.6    20.4
    20.3
      544
    20.3
    
    21.1
    
    3,267
    20.4
    36.5
    1,439
    16.8
    
    35. 1
    
    3,642
    15.5
    1,885
    14. 1
    
    29.5
      282
    10.5
    
    23.7
    
    2,167
    13.5
      392
     2.6
    
    14.7
      280
     3. 3
    
    15.3
    
      672
     2.9
      408
     3. 1
    
    14.6
       66
     2.5
    
    10.9
    
      474
     3.0
       63
     0.4
    
     6. 1
       53
     0.6
    
     6.7
    
      116
     0.5
      175
     1.3
    
    16.7
       39
     1.5
    
    18.4
    
      214
     1.3
    14,940
     100
    
     100
     8,555
     100
    
     100
    
    28,495
     100
    13,352
     100
    
     100
     2,682
     100
    
     100
    
    16,034
     100
    

    -------
    Appendix III-1 (continued)
    Number of
    
    KENTUCKY
    Market Hogs
    Farms
    % farms
    % hogs sold
    Feeder Pigs
    Farms
    % farms
    % pigs sold
    Total Farms
    % farms
    TEXAS
    Market hogs
    Farms
    % farms
    % hogs sold
    Feeder Pigs
    Farms
    % farms
    % pigs sold
    Total Farms
    % farms
    1-9
    
    1,659
    1Z.6
    0.5
    338
    5.5
    0.5
    1,997
    10.3
    
    2,080
    21. 1
    0.7
    298
    8.3
    0.5
    2,378
    17.7
    10-49
    
    5,257
    39.8
    10.0
    2,378
    38.8
    11.2
    7,635
    39.6
    
    3,641
    36.9
    8.2
    1,295
    36.1
    8.0
    4,936
    36.7
    50-99
    
    2,753
    20,8
    14.6
    1,508
    24.6
    16.8
    4,261
    22.0
    
    1,691
    17.2
    10.8
    794
    22. 1
    12.7
    2,485
    18.5
    100-
    199
    
    1,950
    14.8
    20.5
    1, 121
    18.3
    23.8
    3,071
    15.9
    
    1,216
    12.3
    15.7
    600
    16.7
    17.9
    1,816
    13.5
    Hogs Sold
    200-
    499
    
    1, 180
    8.9
    26.7
    642
    10.5
    29.2
    1,822
    9.4
    
    875
    8.7
    23.9
    425
    11.8
    27.6
    1,300
    9.6
    500-
    999
    
    273
    2. 1
    13.8
    118
    1.9
    11.9
    391
    2.0
    
    232
    2.4
    15.3
    117
    3.3
    15. 1
    349
    2.6
    1,000+
    
    130
    1.0
    13.9
    26
    0.4
    6.6
    156
    0.8
    
    134
    1.4
    25.4
    58
    1.7
    18.2
    192
    1.4
    Total
    
    13,202
    100
    100
    6, 131
    100
    100
    19,333
    100
    
    9,869
    100
    100
    3,587
    100
    100
    13,456
    100
    

    -------
                            Appendix III-1 (continued)
    Numb e r of
    
    VIRGINIA
    Market Hogs
    Farms
    % farms
    % hogs sold
    Feeder Pigs
    Farms
    % farms
    % pigs sold
    Total farms
    % farms
    MISSISSIPPI
    Market Kogs
    Farms
    % farms
    % hogs sold
    Feeder Pigs
    Farms
    % farms
    % pigs sold
    Total Farms
    % farms
    1-9
    
    
    1,241
    18. 1
    0.8
    
    178
    8.9
    0.8
    1,419
    16.0
    
    
    800
    21.3
    0.9
    
    132
    11.6
    0.9
    932
    19.0
    10-49
    
    
    2,963
    43.2
    12.3
    
    876
    43.8
    12.3
    3,839
    43.3
    
    
    1,643
    43.6
    10.9
    
    502
    44. 1
    12.6
    2, 145
    43.7
    50-99
    
    
    1, 169
    17.0
    15.4
    
    447
    22.4
    15.4
    1,616
    18.3
    
    
    574
    15.2
    11.4
    
    210
    18.4
    13.6
    784
    16.0
    100-
    199
    
    
    836
    12.2
    19.0
    
    272
    13.6
    19.0
    1, 108-
    12.5
    
    
    416
    11. 1
    16.2
    
    160
    14.0
    20.2
    576
    11.7
    Hogs Sold
    200-
    499
    
    
    485
    7. 1
    28. 1
    
    181
    9.0
    28. 1
    666
    7. 5
    
    
    223
    5.9
    17.9
    
    95
    8.3
    28.4
    318
    6.5
    500-
    999
    
    
    125
    1.8
    10. 1
    
    34
    1.7
    10. 1
    159
    1.8
    
    
    62
    1.6
    12.9
    
    27
    2.4
    11.2
    89
    1.8
    1,000+
    
    
    39
    0.6
    14.3
    
    13
    0.6
    14.3
    52
    0.6
    
    
    47
    1.3
    29.8
    
    13
    1.2
    13. 1
    60
    1.3
    Total
    
    
    6,858
    100
    100
    
    2,001
    100
    100
    8,859
    100
    
    
    3,765
    100
    100
    
    1,139
    100
    100
    4, 904
    100
    Source:  1969 Agricultural Census.   Farms -with gross sales of $2, 500 or more.
    

    -------
     BIBLIOGRAPHIC DATA
     SHEET
    1. Report No.
       EPA 230/1-73-008
                                                                        3* Recipient's Accession No.
    4. Tulc and Subtitle
       Economic Analysis of Proposed Effluent Guidelines  -
                Feedlots Industry
                                                    5. Report Date August, 1973
                                                    (Date  of completion)
                                                    6.
    7. Author(s)
     Milton L.  David,  Richard E.  Seltzer, William D.  Eickhoff
                                                    8. Performing Organization Kept.
                                                      No-     116
    ?. Performing Organization, Name and Address
         Development Planning and Research Associates, Inc.
         P. O.  Box 727
         Manhattan,  Kansas  66502
                                                    10. Project/Task,• Work L'pn No.
                                                      Task Order  No. 2
                                                    11. Contract/Grant No.
                                                      Contract No.
                                                        68-01-1533
    12. Sponsoring Organization Name and Address
         Environmental Protection Agency
         Waterside Mall
         4th and M Street,  S.  W.
         Washington, D. C.  20460  	
                                                    13. Type ot Report & Period
                                                      Covered
                                                           Final Report
                                                    14.
    15. Supplementary Notes
    16. Abstracts
          The feedlots industry is composed of beef,  hog, dairy,  sheep,  layer, broiler,
      turkey, and duck operations.   Numbers of feedlots within each segment  range from
      150 for ducks to over 800, 000 for hogs.  Estimated after-tax return on sales range
      from  zero percent for small turkey operations to 28 percent for small hog operations,
      with the. majority of feedlot operations  ranging between 5 and 15 percent.  All oper-
      ators, except dairymen, are  price-taker s ; dairymen do have some  collective
      bargaining  power.
          Imposition of effluent limitations is expected to impact  primarily the beef, hog
      and dairy operations.  Beef and hog prices are not immediately expected to increase
      because of  lack of bargaining power; milk prices may increase but less than one
      percent.  Effluent controls will accelerate the present trend of small feedlots exiting
    17. Key Words and Document Analysis.  17a. Descriptors
    
      Pollution,  water pollution, effluent, effluent control, agricultural wastes,  feedlots,
      economic, agricultural economics,  economic analysis, cash flow,  demand,  supply,
      prices, fixed costs, variable costs, employment,  community, production capacity,
      fixed investment.
    17b. Idenufiers/Open-EndeJ Terms
                        02  Agriculture, B-agricultural economics,  E-animal husbandly
    I7c.
    18. Availability M.iur.ii nt
         National Technical Information Service
         Springfield,  Virginia  22151
                                        19.
                                        20. .Se^ uruy I 1.1-.-, (lln:
                                           Pa,-c
                                          	l'\r I  \---IHin
                                                              21. .\J. <>t !
                                                                  300
    

    -------
    16.   Abstracts (Continued)
        from the industry.  Small hog producers are expected to be the most
        impacted as the additional investment required is substantial compared
        to the original facilities investment.
    
              Employment and community impacts will be slight as impacted
        resources will be redeployed to large feedlots on existing farms and
        off-farm endeavors.  The.Central States will be  more  seriously impacted
        as they have the majority of small operations.
    
              The impact analysis is based upon a number of assumptions and cost
        estimates which are identified.
                           Protection Agency
             2CO s, - ; ,j Dearborn Street
             Chic- -os  Illinois  6060H
    

    -------