United States
           Environmental Protection
           Agency
               Office of Air Quality
               Planning and Standards
               Research Triangle Park, NC 27711
           Air
Final Report
EPA-452/R-98-002
July 1998
oEPA
ECONOMIC IMPACT AND
REGULATORY FLEXIBILITY
ANALYSES OF THE FINAL
ARCHITECTURAL COATINGS
VOC RULE
                    U.S. Environmental Protection Agency
                    Region 5. Library (PL-12J)
                    77 West Jackson Boulevard, 12th floor
                    Chicago, IL 60604-3590

-------
 :                                 TABLE OF CONTENTS
U
—       Section

J                   Executive Summary	 .  ix
V
              1     Introduction,  Regulatory Background,  and
                    Industry Profile 	  1-1

                    1.1  Introduction	  1-1

                    1.2  Regulatory Background   	  1-2
                         1.2.1   Regulatory Structure  	  1-3

                    1.3  Industry Profile  	  1-5
                         1.3.1   Commodities and VOC Content	  1-5
                         1.3.2   Demand for Architectural Coatings .  .   .  1-8
                                 1.3.2.1  Conceptual View of Coating
                                         Decision	  1-8
                                 1.3.2.2  Substitution Effects  	 1-10
                                 1.3.2.3  Aggregate Demand 	 1-11
                                 1.3.2.4  Coating Users    	 1-11
                         1.3.3   Production of Architectural Coatings   . 1-12
                                 1.3.3.1  Raw Material Inputs   	 1-12
                                 1.3.3.2  Formulations  	 1-15
                                 1.3.3.3  Manufacturers'  Substitution
                                         Options and New
                                         Technologies  	 1-17
                         1.3.4   Industry Conditions 	 1-20
                                 1.3.4.1  Shipments and Manufacturer
                                         Specialization   	 1-20
                                 1.3.4.2  Company Size and Industry
                                         Structure   	1-23

              2     Costs of Proposed Regulation for Architectural
                    Coating Producers  	  2-1

                    2.1  Background	2-1

                    2.2  Overview of Response Options  	  2-2
                         2.2.1   Supply	  2-2
                         2.2.2   Demand	2-4
                    2.3  Cost Analysis   	2-5
                         2.3.1   Costs of Reformulation	2-5
                                 2.3.1.1  Product-Level Reformulation
                                         Cost Estimates	2-8
                                 2.3.1.2  National Reformulation Costs   . 2-14
                                          ill

-------
                   TABLE OF CONTENTS  (continued)

Section                                                         Page

                2.3.2   Exceedance Fee Provision	2-20
                2.3.3   Product Withdrawal   	 2-23
                2.3.4   "Best-Response* Analysis  	 2-24
                2.3.5   Tonnage Exemption 	 2-30

           2.4  Cost Analysis Uncertainties   	 2-30
                2.4.1   Upward Bias	 2-32
                2.4.2   Downward Bias	2-32
                2.4.3   Unknown Directional  Effects  	 2-33

      3     Architectural Coatings Market Analysis 	  3-1

           3.1  Market  Effects  of  Firm Responses to
                Regulation	  3-1
                3.1.1   Model  Execution and  Results  	  3-2
                        3.1.1.1  Baseline  	  3-2
                        3.1.1.2  Quantifying Market Shocks   .   .  3-3

           3.2  Architectural Coatings Industry Employment
                Impacts   	3-10

      4     Traffic Coating User Costs  	  4-1

           4.1  Truck Replacement  Cost Method   	4-2

           4.2  Equipment Retrofit Method   	  4-5

           4.3  National Incremental Cost Calculation   ....  4-5

      5     Social Cost-Effectiveness Analysis 	  5-1

           5.1  Conversion of  Impacts  to Current Dollars  .  .   .  5-5

      6     Small Business Impact Analysis 	  6-1

           6.1  Background and  Affected Entities  	  6-2
                6.1.1   Potentially Affected Entities 	  6-3
                6.1.2   Regulatory Requirements 	  6-5
           6.2  Analysis	  6-6
                6.2.1   Baseline Market Presence of  Small
                        Architectural  Coatings Producers  .  .   .  6-6
                6.2.2   VOC Content of Small Business Products:
                        Technology and Specialization Effects  . 6-11
                6.2.3   Costs Associated With Regulatory
                        Compliance	6-17
                6.2.4   Reformulation  Cost Impact Estimates .   . 6-18
                        6.2.4.1  Small  Business  Impacts  Under
                                 "Reformulation-Only" Option   . 6-22
                                 IV

-------
                   TABLE OF CONTENTS (continued)

Section                                                         Page

                6.2.5   Cost Impacts Across Market Segments .  .  6-23
                6.2.6   Average Cost Impacts for Small
                        Company	6-25
                6.2.7   Potential Factors Mitigating Small
                        Business Impacts:  Exceedance Fee,
                        Withdrawal, and Tonnage Exemption . .  .  6-27
                        6.2.7.1 Fee and Withdrawal  Options  .  ,  6-27
                        6.2.7.2 Tonnage Exemption  	  6-29
           6.3  Regulatory  Alternatives to  Reduce Impacts   .  .  6-31
                6.3.1   Selection of VOC Content Limits and
                        Coating Categories  	  6-33
                6.3.2   Low-Volume Exemption Option 	  6-34
                6.3.3   Exceedance Fee Compliance Option  . .  .  6-38
                        6.3.3.1 Exceedance  Fee  Rate  	6-41
                6.3.4   Extended Compliance Time for Small
                        Businesses	6-44
                6.3.5   Compliance Variances	6-45
                6.3.6   Selection of Recordkeeping and Reporting
                        Requirements	6-47
           6.4  Small Business  Impact Summary   	  6-49

      7     Epilogue	   7-1

           7.1  New Product Categories	   7-1

           7.2  Categories  with Higher  VOC  Content  Limits   .  .   7-6

           7.3  Summary   	   7-7

      8     References	   8-1

Appendices

      A     Market  Definition, Demand Estimation,
           and Data	A-l

      B     Summary of  Reformulation Cost Estimates from
           Public  Comments   	   B-l

      C     Calculation of Regulation-Induced Costs when
           Reformulation Normally Occurs at Fixed Time
           Intervals	C-l

      D     Methodology for Computing Market and Welfare
           Adjustments	   D-1

-------
                           LIST OF FIGURES

Number                                                          Page
  1-1   Comprehensive classification of emissions
        from consumer and commercial products	1-2
  1-2   Inputs generally used in the manufacture
        of a solventborne coating	1-16
  1-3   Inputs generally used in the manufacture
        of a waterborne coating	1-16
  1-4   Approximate volume relationships of coating
        ingredients	1-18
  1-5   Location of manufacturing establishments
        in the paints and allied products
        industry in 1987:   SIC 2851	1-27

  2-1   Basic stages of architectural coating reformulation
        (prototype firm and product)   	2-4
  2-2   Fee versus reformulation  	2-22

  4-1   Cost schedules with and without accelerated
        replacement	4-4
  4-2   Replacement cost schedules with and without
        equipment retrofit  	  4-6

  6-1   Chain of ownership  	6-4
                                 VI

-------
                           LIST OF TABLES

Number                                                          Page


  1-1      Average VOC  Content  for Architectural Coatings
           Expected  to  Be  Covered by Proposed Regulation   .  .  .   1-7
  1-2      Consumers of Architectural Coatings   	  1-12
  1-3      Percentage of Solvent  in Conventional and
           Reformulated Organic Solventborne Coatings  	  1-19
  1-4      Value  Shipped of Potentially Regulated Paint
           and Allied Products: 1981 Through 1991	1-21
  1-5      Number of Companies, Establishments,  and
           Producer  Specialization—Paint and Allied
           Products:  1987  	1-24
  1-6      Commodity Production in 1982: Paint and
           Allied Products  	  1-25
  1-7      Large  Firm Dominance and Numbers of Companies
           and Establishments in  the Paint  and Allied
           Products  Industry:   1987  	  1-27
  1-8      Number of Companies  and Establishments in
           the Coatings Industry,  Selected  Years,
           1972-1991   	1-28
  1-9      Recent Acquisitions  in the Coatings Industry  ....  1-29

  2-1      Table  of  Standards	2-6
  2-2      National  Costs:  Reformulation-Only Scenario  ....  2-19
  2-3      Architectural Coatings Market Segments Baseline
           Data	2-27
  2-4      Best-Response Option Analysis—Survey Population:
           Fee =  $2,200/ton	2-28
  2-5      Reformulation Cost Analysis Uncertainties  	  2-31

  3-1      Regulatory Effects on  Architectural Coatings
           Market Output and Prices  	   3-6
  3-2      Architectural Coatings Market Welfare Effects   .  .  .   3-9
  3-3      Estimated Employment Effects  	  3-11
                                VI1

-------
                     LIST OF TABLES  (continued)

Number                                                           Page

  4-1      National Incremental Cost of Traffic Coating
           Equipment Replacement and Retrofits—Medium
           Stripers	4-7
  4-2      National Incremental Cost of Traffic Coating
           Equipment Replacement and Retrofits—Large
           Stripers	4-9
  4-3      National Incremental Cost Summary for Traffic
           Coating Equipment   	4-11

  5-1      Social Cost-Effectiveness Estimates   	   5-4
  5-2      Conversion of Summary Impacts to 1996 Dollars   .  .  .   5-5

  6-1      Small Business Presence in the Architectural
           Coatings Market:   Survey Population   	   6-7
  6-2      Baseline VOC Content	6-12
  6-3      Specialization-Based Average VOC Content:  Small
           Business Products   	  6-15
  6-4      Small Business Costs by Market Segment:
           Reformulation Option Only   	6-19
  6-5      Average Regulatory Impact by Firm Size—
           "Reformulation-Only* Scenario   	  6-26
  6-6      Average Regulatory Impact for Small Companies—
           "Best-Response* Scenario  	  6-28

  7-1      Table of Standards:   Interim vs. Final	7-4
                                Vlll

-------
                       EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

     Under Title I of the Clean Air Act of  1990, the U.S.
Environmental Protection Agency  (EPA) is developing
regulations to reduce volatile organic compound  (VOC)
emissions from various consumer and commercial products.  One
of the first categories of consumer and commercial products to
be regulated is architectural coatings.  This report analyzes
the costs and economic impacts of the final architectural
coatings rule.
     The general purpose of the regulation  is to reduce the
flow of VOCs into the atmosphere from the use and disposal of
architectural coating products.  These emissions are
distinguished from the manufacturing-related emissions that
are controlled by other forms of regulation  (as are emissions
to land and water).
     VOC emissions are regulated because of their contribution
to the formation of ground-level ozone.  Elevated levels of
ozone degrade air quality and pose a variety of health risks
to exposed populations.

ES.l  COMPLIANCE ACTIONS

     The regulation imposes a set of standards for VOC content
for individual architectural coating products.  Products that
exceed the limits imposed by these standards must either be
brought into compliance with the limits, have an exceedance
fee assessed on the product's VOC content above the limit,  or
                              ix

-------
be withdrawn from the market.  These actions, however, can be
avoided for products subject to the small tonnage exemption.

ES.2  COMPLIANCE COSTS

     The number of compliance actions was estimated using
survey data on VOC content and sales volumes for almost
5,000 architectural coating products manufactured by
116 companies.  The surveyed products constitute about
three-quarters of industry output.  The survey data were used
to estimate the compliance activity for the products and
manufacturers not covered in the survey and is thereby the
basis for the national estimate of costs.
     Initially, the regulatory impacts were viewed in a very
restrictive light, assuming that reformulation down to the
standards is the only option available to producers.  The
aggregate costs of this restrictive option were then computed
to give a benchmark measure of regulatory costs under a
restrictive set of conditions.  The costs in Table ES-1
present both the initial one-time expenditure for the
reformulations and the costs expressed in annualized terms.
     TABLE ES-1.  NATIONAL COST FOR ARCHITECTURAL COATINGS
                  PRODUCERS-REFORMULATION-ONLY

   Total  Initial  Expenditure        Total Annualized Cost
   	($1991)	($1991)	
          204.0  million                   34.2 million
     The analysis was expanded by progressively shedding the
restrictive assumptions of forced reformulation.  First, the
exceedance fee option was incorporated, taking into account
that producers may choose to pay an exceedance fee rather than
reformulate if it is a less costly alternative for them.

-------
Then, the least-cost compliance option  (fee or reformulation)
was compared with benefit streams  (net revenues) to determine
if the least-cost option is also profitable.  If the value of
the benefit stream is less than the cost of compliance, firms
are assumed to remove the products from the market as a
best-response strategy.  Alternative response options reduce
the cost of the regulation by approximately 20 percent for the
architectural coating producers included in the survey.  Cost
reductions are likely to be greater for the nonsurvey
population and are further reduced when market-level responses
are factored in (see below).  Most of the cost savings is
attributable to adopting the exceedance fee, which is
projected to be the compliance option for a number of products
that are either very small in volume or have a VOC content
relatively close to the limit.  Because the fee is generally
adopted for relatively small sources of VOC "exceedance," the
effect on VOC emissions reductions is projected to be
relatively small.

ES.3  MARKET EFFECTS

     The compliance actions lead to a reallocation of
society's resources toward VOC controls, which imposes
opportunity costs directly on the producers and indirectly on
other members of society as producers act,  markets respond,
and prices and output change.  The purpose of the
architectural coatings market analysis is to characterize the
reallocation of resources and quantify them in
dollar-denominated terms to assess the distribution of costs
and economic impacts of the regulation.
     The collective effect of some producers removing
unprofitable products and some producers bearing a per-unit
fee on output will contract the aggregate supply of
                              XI

-------
architectural coatings and lead to changes in market prices
and quantities.  The optimal best-response actions and
resulting market outcomes will determine how the welfare costs
of the policy are distributed across producer groups,
consumers, and the government sector.
     Several scenarios were modeled for the standards.   In
general, market model results indicate a very small change in
baseline market conditions as a result of the regulation.
This derives from the expectation that aggregate costs of the
regulation are a small share of aggregate industry costs.
However, because there is a high degree of producer
heterogeneity within the architectural coatings sector, the
costs for some producers may be large. The distribution of
impacts across affected parties is presented in Table ES-2.

              TABLE ES-2.   MARKET IMPACTS SUMMARY

 Aggregate Welfare Effects on....                (MM $1991)
 Architectural coating producers                   -22.0
 Architectural coating consumers                    -4.3
 Government (fee receipts)                          +4.0
 Net social welfare effect ("social cost*)         -22.3

     A portion of the cost for architectural coating producers
is passed on to consumers in the form of higher prices, which
lowers their welfare.  An important impact to consider is the
effect of the fee payments.  While these payments constitute
losses for the producers paying the fee  (less the amount they
are able to pass on to the consumer via higher prices), these
fee payments are simply transfer payments to the government
and therefore do not constitute a net increase in social
costs.  In other words, while the fee serves as a private cost
for firms that do not reduce VOCs to the statutory limit and a

                              xii

-------
continuing incentive  for producers  to reduce VOCs to  the
limit, it does not constitute  an allocation of  society's
resources to a particular use  as, in contrast,  the allocation
of resources for reformulation does.
     The net social cost estimate is substantially lower than
the annualized cost estimate under  the reformulation-only
scenario described above.  The market analysis  demonstrates
the potential for substantial  cost  savings due  to adopting the
fee alternative and how this cost savings is likely to accrue
especially to producers of small volume products.  Moreover,
this cost savings is  not expected to have a significant impact
on undercutting aggregate emissions reduction targets.

ES.4  TRAFFIC COATING USER COSTS

     The economic analysis up  to this point has focused
entirely on the primary impacts of  the regulation, those borne
directly by producers in the architectural coatings industry
in the form of higher costs and indirectly by the consumers of
architectural products in the  form of higher prices.   The
driving force of those impacts is the requirement that, except
for products subject  to the tonnage exemption,  noncompliant
products must either be reformulated to a compliant VOC level,
be subject to a fee on the excess VOCs over the allowable
level, or be withdrawn from the market.   However,  this
analysis considered a type of  secondary impact,  one that is
caused by the costs that users of a newly compliant product
must incur to purchase the special equipment necessary to
apply the compliant coating.   The secondary impact analysis
focuses exclusively on users of traffic marking paints,
primarily government entities such as state transportation
departments,  for whom the costs of switching application
                             XI11

-------
equipment ("striper" trucks) are thought to be potentially
significant.
     Traffic coating user costs are summarized in Table ES-3.
Costs are estimated as the incremental cost associated with
the accelerated replacement of striper trucks and are
expressed both in terms of the present value of the one-time
acceleration ($53.2 million total) and on an annualized basis
($3.7 million).
  TABLE ES-3.  NATIONAL INCREMENTAL COST  SUMMARY FOR TRAFFIC
                   COATING EQUIPMENT ($1996)

 Striper Type              Present Value of     Annualized
                                 Cost              Cost
 Medium (see Table 4-1)        $42,844,912         $2,999,144
 Large (see Table 4-2)         $10,393,011           $727,511
 Total                        $53,237,923         $3,726,655
ES.5 SOCIAL COST-EFFECTIVENESS

     The social cost estimates from the market analysis and
the estimate of traffic coating user costs can be used to
compute measures of the social cost-effectiveness of the
regulation.  The distinction of "social" cost-effectiveness is
made to illuminate the fact that the costs evaluated are the
net costs imposed on society (i.e., the net welfare costs
estimated in the architectural coatings market plus the
resource costs incurred by traffic coating users to switch
application equipment).
     Cost-effectiveness results are summarized in Table ES-4.
Emission reduction effects of the regulation are estimated by
taking the national target for VOC emission reductions from
                              xiv

-------
        TABLE ES-4.  SOCIAL COST-EFFECTIVENESS  SUMMARY

    Social Cost      Estimated Emissions   Social Cost per Mg
       ($1991)           Reduction (Mg)            ($1991)
    25.6 million           103,471      	247	
architectural coatings and modifying that total to account for
market responses  (fee adoption and changes  in output levels).
     This estimate allows for an evaluation of
cost-effectiveness implications of the fee  option.  Allowing
the fee reduces social costs by about $12 million but foregoes
about 1,802 Mg of emissions reduction, about 1.7 percent of
the targeted reductions.  Dividing the cost savings by
foregone reductions approximates the marginal social cost of
the foregone reductions.  This figure is $6,580/Mg, which is
substantially higher than the $247/Mg average social
cost-effectiveness measure reported above.  This difference
indicates that the fee's main effect is to  reduce the very
most expensive emission reductions without  substantially
undercutting the achievement of emissions reduction.
     For external reporting purposes, the economic impacts are
reported in 1996 dollars.  Costs are converted from the base
year used in the analysis  (1991) to 1996 using the Gross
Domestic Product  (GDP) price deflator.  The conversion results
are presented in Table ES-5.

   TABLE ES-5.  CONVERSION  OF  SUMMARY  IMPACTS TO  1996 DOLLARS

	Impact Estimate	$1991	$1996	
 Net social cost           $25.6  million    $29.2 million
 Net social cost per Mg    $247/Mg          $282/Mg
 of emissions reduction
                               xv

-------
ES.6 SMALL BUSINESS IMPACTS AND REGULATORY FLEXIBILITY
     ANALYSIS

     The potential for significant impacts on small businesses
of the regulation arises from two primary sources:

     •  Products made  by small  producers,  on average,  have a
        higher VOC content  than the  industry average.
     •  The costs of reformulating products  to comply with the
        regulation are fixed and thereby impose higher average
        costs on small volume coatings.

     The first problem is related to small producers' tendency
to specialize in coatings categories that are naturally higher
in VOC content and to their tendency to concentrate in the
"high-VOC" end of the distribution of products within a given
category.  Thus, the potential for disproportionate impacts of
VOC reduction regulation on small businesses follows partly
from the fact that small businesses contribute a
disproportionate amount of the aggr«gate VOC emissions that
are targeted for reduction.
     The second problem follows from the nature of
reformulation costs.  A coating's formula is the product of an
intellectual capital investment, much like the development of
a drug or a  computer software product.  The cost of the
investment follows directly from the level of effort necessary
to revise the formula to meet both the VOC standards imposed
by the regulation and performance standards imposed by the
marketplace.  This level of effort is essentially independent
of the quantity of the product that is eventually sold.
Therefore, the relative impacts on smaller volume products is,
by definition, greater.
     The data used in this analysis suggest that these two
primary factors are relevant in the case of small
architectural coating producers.  The average VOC content of

                              xvi

-------
the products made by the  small  business producers  in the
survey is 75 percent higher  than the average VOC content of
all products combined  (see Table ES-6).  A little  over half of
the difference in the  averages  is attributed to the
specialization of small producers in high-VOC content product
categories,  with the remainder  attributed to the tendency for
small  businesses to produce  higher VOC products within each
product group.  Moreover, the average product volume of
products made by small businesses is less than 20  percent of
the average product volume for  the entire survey population,
implying much larger average reformulation costs  (see
Table  ES-7).  Thus, without  mitigating factors, the impacts on
some small businesses  are potentially significant.

                TABLE ES-6.   BASELINE VOC CONTENT
Size
Category*
All products
Small business
products
VOC
Emissions
(Mg)
344,059
21,431
Sales
(kL)
1,853,623
65,914
Average VOC
Content
(g/L)
186
325
a The survey had 116 respondents and 36 of those identified themselves as
  having under $10 million in annual sales.  Twelve survey respondents did
  not report company size.
Source: Industry Insights.  Architectural and Industrial Maintenance
       Surface Coatings VOC Emissions Inventory Survey.  Prepared for
       National Paint and Coatings Association in cooperation with the
       AIM Regulatory Negotiation Industry Caucus. Final Draft Report.
       1993.
     At  proposal,  the Agency included specialized coating
categories  and limits designed  to  preserve niche product
markets.  To  evaluate whether further steps were still needed
to accommodate niche market coatings,  the Agency requested
that commenters identify any additional specialty coatings
                               xvn

-------
that would not comply with applicable VOC content
requirements.  The Agency also requested comment on whether to
include an "exceedance fee" in the final rule, which would
allow companies the option of paying a fee, based on the
amount that VOC content limits are exceeded, instead of
achieving the limit.  In addition, the Agency requested
comment on the concept of a low volume cut-off, under which a
coating might be exempt from regulation.  In the final rule,
the Agency has included the exceedance fee compliance option
and a provision  that enables each manufacturer to claim as
exempt a specified amount of VOC per year  (known as the
tonnage exemption).  Also, in response to public comments, the
Agency created seven new niche product categories and
increased the VOC content limits for four product categories
in the final rule.  The Agency also added an extended period
for compliance after promulgation to allow additional time for
reformulations.  These provisions are designed to mitigate
rule impacts on small businesses' low production volumes and
to allow for the preservation of several niche markets.
However, based on the limited data available to the Agency,
only the mitigating impact of exceedance fees can be
quantified.
     The analysis shows that, when reformulation is the only
option for compliance, the cost/revenue ratio is estimated to
be 2.5 percent on average  (see Table ES-7).  When the
alternative compliance options of the exceedance fee or
product withdrawal are considered, the ratio decreases to
2.0 percent  (see Table ES-8).  This ratio would decrease
further if the cost effects of the additional niche product
categories, use of the tonnage exemption, and reduction in
cost to reformulate due to resin supplier assistance could be
specifically quantified.
                             XVlll

-------
      TABLE  ES-7.  AVERAGE REGULATORY  IMPACT BY  FIRM SIZE-
                   "REFORMULATION-ONLY*  SCENARIO*
                                        Industry          Small Firm
                                        Average            Average

 Revenue" ($1991)                        38,990,000         4,614,000

 Number of products"                           42.4              27.5

 Number of products  facing major                9.9               7.8
    reformulation0

 Annualized reformulation cost5  ($1991)       144,272            113,669

 Ratio of annualized reformulation              0.4               2.5
 cost to revenues (percent)

* The survey has 116 respondents and 36 of those identified themselves as
  having under $10 million in annual sales.  Twelve survey respondents did
  not report company size.
b Data for revenues and products per firm were based on data reported in
  Table 6-1.  The number of products per firm is based on the total number
  of products for which quantity data are available.
c This number represents two-thirds of the products over the 1998 TOS.
  Industry experts estimate that approximately two-thirds of the products
  with VOC contents exceeding the TOS limits face a 'major' reformulation.
d Annualized cost of reformulation is the number of major reformulations
  multiplied by the annualized reformulation cost estimate per  product of
  $14,573  ($1991).

Source:  Industry Insights.  Architectural and Industrial Maintenance
        Surface Coatings VOC Emissions Inventory Survey.  Prepared for
        National Paint and Coatings Association in cooperation  with the
        AIM Regulatory Negotiation Industry Caucus.  Final Draft Report.
        1993.
      The Agency prepared analyses  to support both  the proposed

and  final rules that are equivalent to those required by  the

Regulatory Flexibility  Act (RFA) as modified by the Small

Business Regulatory Enforcement  Fairness  Act of 1996 (SBREFA).

The  Agency undertook these analyses because of the large

presence of small entities in the  architectural coatings

industry and because the initial impact analysis indicated

that there could be a significant  economic impact  on a

substantial number of small entities if mitigating regulatory

options were not adopted for the rule.  After evaluating

public comment  on the proposed mitigating options,  EPA made a
                                 xix

-------
        TABLE ES-8.  AVERAGE REGULATORY IMPACT FOR SMALL
               COMPANIES-'BEST-RESPONSE* SCENARIO
Compliance
Strategy
Reformulate
Fee
Withdrawal
Total
Average percent
Percent of All
Constrained
Survey Products
Selecting
Option
60.5%
35.5%
4.0%
100.0%
of sales
"Expected*
Number of
Products
Selecting
Strategy"
4.7
2.8
0.3
7.8

Average
Compliance
Cost per
Product
($1991)
14,573
7,197b
12,705C
11,879

Compliance
Cost
($1991)
68,767
19,936
3,955
92,658
2.0%
a Equals average number of constrained products for small companies (7.8)
  multiplied by percentage of all constrained products  in the survey
  selecting each strategy.
b Average fee cost computed by taking the average fee rate ($0.084/L),
  multiplying by the average size per small company product (65,914 L),
  and adding the recordkeeping cost per product of $590.
c Equals the average value of foregone profits for the  46 surveyed
  products that select the fee as the best-response strategy.
number of  changes to the proposed rule to further mitigate the
rule's small  business impacts.   As a result,  the  Agency
believes that it is highly unlikely that the  rule will have a
significant economic impact  on  a substantial  number of small
entities.  However, in light of the Agency's  inability to
quantify the  effect of the mitigating options,  the EPA has
elected to conduct a regulatory flexibility analysis and to
prepare a  SBREFA compliance  guide to eliminate  any potential
dispute on whether EPA has fulfilled SBREFA requirements.

ES.7  EPILOGUE

     Because  regulatory development is an evolving process,
the final  Table of Standards for VOC content  limits differs
slightly from the interim Table of Standards  used in the
analysis reported here.  The main difference  between the two
                                xx

-------
sets of standards is the addition of seven new categories in
the final standards and an increase in the VOC content limits
for three categories.
     By and large, new categories were added to accommodate
specialty products that were previously included in other
categories with lower VOC limits.  As a result, some products
that would be over the limit in the previous category, thereby
necessitating a compliance action  (reformulate, fee payment,
withdrawal),  are no longer constrained by the regulation.
Therefore, in most cases the addition of the new categories
reduces the number of required compliance actions and, as a
result, also cuts compliance costs.  In addition, raising the
VOC limits in the other categories reduces compliance actions
and costs as well.
     However, one of the new product categories, concrete
curing and sealing (CCS) compounds, applies to products that
were considered outside of the regulated universe in the
economic analysis presented in this report.  Therefore, the
costs associated with the compliance actions required for
those products are not estimated in the analysis.  If they
were, the cost estimate would be larger.
     Data were available to approximate cost effects for only
two of the seven new product categories.  One of these was the
CCS category, which allowed for an estimate of the
corresponding increase in costs just described.  The other new
product category for which data were obtained is zone
markings.  The original 1991 emissions inventory provided data
to analyze the cost reductions due to the increase in content
limits for three product categories.  Taken together,  the
available data allowed for quantification of a $580,000
(1991 dollars) net increase in the estimate of annual social
costs.  However, this increase in cost must be considered
against the unquantified decrease in costs from the expected
fall in compliance activity in the five other new categories
                              xxi

-------
for which data were unavailable.  Without additional data, it
is difficult to conclude whether the cost reductions from
those categories will together outweigh the net cost increases
quantified.  Given that the social cost effects quantified
here are less than 3 percent of the total estimated social
costs of the regulation, factors that reduce  (or reverse the
sign) of these costs lead to the conclusion that the total
social cost estimate is not greatly affected by the
differences between the interim standards used in the analysis
and the final standards issued in the rule.
                              xxii

-------
                           SECTION 1
   INTRODUCTION,  REGULATORY BACKGROUND,  AND INDUSTRY PROFILE
1.1  INTRODUCTION

     Under Title I of the Clean Air Act of 1990, the U.S.
Environmental Protection Agency  (EPA) is developing
regulations to reduce volatile organic compound  (VOC)
emissions from various consumer and commercial products.  One
of the first categories of consumer and commercial products to
be regulated is architectural coatings.
     This report analyzes the economic impacts of the final
architectural coating regulation.  Section 183(e)(l)(B) of the
Clean Air Act Amendments of 1990 defines a consumer or
commercial product as
     any substance, product (including paints, consumer
     and commercial products,  and solvents), or article
     (including any container or packaging) held by any
     person, the use, consumption, storage, disposal,
     destruction, or decomposition of which may result in
     the release of volatile organic compounds.
Thus, the general purpose of the regulation is to reduce the
flow of VOCs into the atmosphere from consumption and disposal
of products that contain VOCs.  Figure 1-1 shows the
dissipative emissions and the disposal emissions into the air
that are the target of this regulation.1  These emissions are
                              1-1

-------
                                                agro-chtmleal*
                   InduslriaVantrgy
                   Mt I (fit Is us* t consumption (pollution
                  takodfetf in coniMrcial and eontumtr goods)
                                                application to soils of agro-chi nlcils
                                                             Araa-sourc*
                                                          agricultural tmissions
Point- and ar«a-sourct
production (missions
Oisslpalivt
tmissions
Disposal emission*
                             AIR, LAND. AND WATER
  Figure 1-1.   Comprehensive classification of emissions from
                 consumer and commercial  products.

Source:  Adapted from Stigliani,  William M.  Chemical Emissions from the
        Processing and Use of Materials:  The  Need for an Integrated
        Emissions Accounting System.   Ecological Economics £(4):325-341.
        1990.   (Figure 2).
distinguished from the manufacturing-related emissions that
are  controlled by other  forms  of regulation.   The  regulatory
structure  is presented here followed  by an  overview of the
architectural coatings industry.

1.2   REGULATORY BACKGROUND

      Section 183(e)(3)(A)  directs the EPA to list  categories
of consumer or commercial  products that account for at least
                                  1-2

-------
80 percent of VOC emissions on a reactivity-adjusted basis in
ozone nonattainment areas.  The EPA divided this category list
into four groups and established priorities for regulation.
Architectural coatings is in the first group of categories to
be regulated.
     The design of regulatory strategies to reduce VOCs
emitted by architectural coatings is shaped in specific ways
by the Clean Air Act as amended.  Two components of the
legislation are of particular importance:
     •  determining regulated entities and
     •  establishing best available controls.
     Regulations developed under Section 183(e) may be imposed
only with respect to "manufacturers, processors, wholesale
distributors, or importers of consumer or commercial products
for sale or distribution in interstate commerce in the United
States" or certain entities that supply such products to the
former Sections 183(e)(1) (C) and 183(e) (3) (B) .  The definition
of regulated entities  excludes retailers and users.
     The regulations affecting architectural coatings will
require best available controls.  The EPA Administrator, on
the basis of "technological and economic feasibility, health,
environmental, and energy impacts," will determine the desired
degree of emissions reduction that
     is achievable through the application of the most
     effective equipment, measures, processes, methods,
     systems or techniques, including chemical
     reformulation, product or feedstock substitution,
     repackaging, and  directions for use, consumption,
     storage, or disposal.   (Section 183[e][l]).
1.2.1  Regulatory Structure

     One hundred sixteen architectural coatings manufacturers
responded to a survey  conducted by the National Paint and
                              1-3

-------
Coatings Association for products manufactured and their VOC
contents.2  The Architectural and Industrial Maintenance
Surface Coatings VOC Emissions  Inventory  Survey (the survey)
provides VOC content information and 1990 sales quantities by
product.  Based in part on these data, EPA is  promulgating VOC
content limit standards, which  manufacturers and importers
will be required to meet in  1999.  Once the regulation becomes
law, manufacturers and importers of architectural coatings
subject to the regulation must  limit the  VOC content per liter
of coating to the standards  specified  for each coating product
they manufacture.  The EPA has  included an option of allowing
manufacturers and importers  to  choose  to  pay an exceedance fee
instead of meeting the limit for a particular  product
category.  Another option manufacturers and importers have is
to use a tonnage exemption to claim a  set amount of product as
exempt from VOC limits.  The VOC content  limits are presented
in the Table of Standards  (TOS) for 1999  in Section 2
(Table 2-1).  The limits specified in  this table were used in
this economic impact analysis.  They cover all the major
architectural coatings categories as well as certain special
purpose coating products for which a less stringent limit is
granted in order for the coating to adequately perform its
designed purpose (e.g., high-temperature  coatings).
     Architectural coatings  manufacturers who  choose to pay a
fee on their products that do not meet the standards will pay
the fee on the VOC content of the product that is in excess of
the limit."  The fee rate is $2,500 (1996 dollars,  adjusted to
$2,200 in 1991 dollars) per  metric ton (Mg) of excess VOCs.
Fees will be paid semi-annually and will  be placed in a
"special fund* specified under  Section 183(e).   If EPA is able
     •Excess VOCs are defined as the maximum VOC content of the coating,
as applied,  in grains per liter of coating, less water and exempt compounds,
minus the applicable VOC standard.
                              1-4

-------
to obtain these funds through a subsequent Congressional
appropriation they may be used by the Administrator to support
the administration of the regulation or to promote additional
VOC emission reductions from architectural coatings through
technological development grants, award programs, or other
means.
     This report includes an overview of the architectural
coatings industry, products, and technologies and an analysis
of the economic impacts on the affected entities and the
industry as a result of the TOS VOC content limits, exceedance
fees, and tonnage exemption.  An economic model of the
architectural coatings industry is developed to obtain
estimates of the potential price and quantity changes
associated with the regulation.  In addition, a Regulatory
Flexibility Analysis is conducted, which estimates the impacts
of the regulation on small businesses and presents
alternatives that may be implemented to mitigate those
impacts.

1.3  INDUSTRY PROFILE

     This profile of the architectural coatings industry
describes commodities and VOC content, demand for
architectural coatings, production of architectural coatings,
and industry conditions.
1.3.1  Commodities and VOC Content
     The "architectural coatings* regulation applies primarily
to products that the U.S. Census Bureau also categorizes as
architectural coatings, but some products in the Census
categories of special purpose coatings and miscellaneous
allied paint products are affected as well.3  Unless  otherwise
indicated,  the term "architectural coatings* is used
                              1-5

-------
throughout this report to indicate the entire group  of
regulated products.  Product categories covered under the
regulation are listed in Table 1-1.*  The products are grouped
into the three Census categories in which they are found.b  As
indicated, the largest quantity of regulated coatings is
included in the architectural coatings category, but some
coatings are classified with the special purpose and allied
paint products categories, which also include other  products
not covered by this regulation such as marine paints and
putty.
     Examples of Census-defined architectural coatings, all of
which are represented in Table 1-1, include exterior and
interior organic solventborne and waterborne tints,  enamels,
undercoats, clear finishes, stains, and architectural
lacquers.  These coatings are used for general purpose  on-site
application to residential, commercial, institutional,  and
industrial structures.  They are intended for ordinary  use and
exposure and provide protection and decoration.
     Special purpose coatings are similar to architectural
coatings in that they can be classified as stock or  shelf
goods, rather than formulated to customer specifications,  as
are OEM coatings.  The difference is that they are formulated
for special applications or environmental conditions such as
extreme temperatures, chemicals, fumes, fungi, or corrosive
conditions.
     VOC content varies substantially between specific  types
of coating products.  Most of this variety is due to the  type
of solvent used in the coating and the ratio of the  solvent to
other ingredients in the formulation.  Based on the  1990
     bSee Appendix A for a detailed explanation of products for regulation
and their corresponding Census classification.
                              1-6

-------
 TABLE  1-1.
AVERAGE VOC  CONTENT  FOR  ARCHITECTURAL COATINGS  TO
         BE COVERED BY REGULATION
                                               Sales-Weighted Average VOC Content
                                                              (g/L)
 Product  Category
                                Organic Solvent
                                                                     Waterborne
 Architectural  coatings
    Exterior flat architectural  coatings
    Exterior nonflat architectural  coatings
    Interior flat architectural  coatings
    Interior nonflat architectural  coatings
    Semitransparent stains
    Opaque stains
    Undercoaters
    Primers
    Sealers
    Waterproofing sealers,  clear
    Waterproofing sealers,  opaque
    Quick dry undercoaters,  primers,  and
      sealers
    Bituminous coatings
    High performance architectural  coatings
    Roof coatings
    Lacquer
    Varnish

 Special purpose/industrial maintenance
    Coatings
    Swimming pool coatings
    Dry fog coatings
    Mastic texture coatings
    Metallic pigmented coatings
    Fire retardant coatings
    Antigraffiti
    Concrete curing compounds
    Form release compounds
    Graphic arts coatings
    High-temperature coatings
    Industrial maintenance  coatings
    Multicolored coatings
    Pretreatment wash primers
    Sanding sealers
    Shellacs
    Traffic marking paints

 Allied paint products
    Below ground wood preservatives
    Semitransparent wood preservatives
    Clear wood preservatives
    Opaque wood preservatives	
                                        336
                                        404
                                        315
                                        413
                                        527
                                        429
                                        379
                                        374
                                        607
                                        659
                                        242
                                        441

                                        290
                                        431
                                        269
                                        667
                                        481
                                        554
                                        365
                                        278
                                        461
                                          a
                                        577
                                        717
                                        601
                                        386
                                        560
                                        392
                                        321
                                        718
                                        531
                                        539
                                        398
                                        541
                                        591
                                        493
                                        446
 68
 76
 .48
 74
 85
 56
 41
 48
 41
200
  a
 31

  4
113
 28
300
143
  a
149
107
  a
 23
131
 71
  a
 42
  a
112
  a
  a
192
  a
 85
  a
 67
419
  a
*  Sales-weighted average VOC content not available.

Source: Industry Insights.   Architectural  and Industrial Maintenance Surface
        Coatings VOC Emissions Inventory Survey.  Prepared for the National Paint
        and Coatings Association in Cooperation with the AIM Regulatory Negotiation
        Industry Caucus.   Final Draft Report.   1993.
                                       1-7

-------
survey data collected,  the  sales-weighted average VOC contents
for surveyed coating products  are listed in Table 1-1.c<5
1.3.2  Demand for Architectural Coatings
     1.3.2.1  Conceptual View  of Coating Decision.   The demand
for architectural coatings  derives from the demand for the
treatment of architectural  surfaces.   Surface treatment
services include not only coating treatment,  but also
noncoating treatment alternatives such as wallpaper or
exterior siding.  While the choice among coating alternatives
is emphasized below, it is  implicitly recognized that the
substitution between coating and noncoating surface treatments
is possible as well.
     The coatings themselves are an input into the production
of surface treatment services,  the final product of interest.
Each surface possesses  certain attributes that affect the
demand for surface  treatment.   These include surface material
(substrate), age, exposure  (e.g.,  weather,  chemicals), and
other physical factors  that intrinsically affect the relative
performance of treatment alternatives.
     In an economic decisionmaking context,  we think of the
owner of the surface as seeking to maximize the utility
derived from the services provided by the surface (i.e.,
shelter, decoration, etc.).  Let process i indicate the
activity of treating a  surface defined by the attributes
above.  Through this process,  labor,  capital,  and materials
are employed to treat the surface.  Thus we can characterize
     'Sales-weighted average VOC content is
                      (VOC Content^ •  (Sales)i
t
                              (Sales)i
                           i-l
where VOC content is equal to the percentage by weight,  sales are measured
in pounds per year, and n equals the number of product categories.

                               1-8

-------
the production of a unit* of surface  treatment  through process
i as follows:
                         Qi  =  Q(L,K,XJ

where Qi is the surface area unit (e.g., 1,000 ft2)  treated
using process i and L, K, and Xt are the quantities of labor,
capital, and material  (e.g.,  coatings)  used to produce Q^.
     For the processes that include  coatings application,
assume there is a fixed proportions  relationship between  each
input and output, determined  by  the  type of coating being
used.  For example, process A requires  1 gallon of coating A,
40 hours of labor, and 10 units  of capital  to  cover a unit
area of a given surface type.  Therefore, for  a given set of
input prices, there is a (constant)  per-unit cost of
treatment.  Costs of noncoating  alternatives can be similarly
computed.  Considering all n  possible treatment alternative
for a given surface generates an array  of costs  (C^Cj, . . . ,Cn) .
     Each owner/consumer places  a subjective value on the
outcome of each treatment alternative.  This value derives
from such factors as innate preferences for the visual appeal
of treatment alternatives and perceptions of the structural
quality and durability.  For  example, consumer A may prefer
the look of glossy solvent-based coatings to flat water-based
coatings and/or may perceive  other differences in product
quality.  The consumer explicitly or implicitly monetizes
these preferences, and the associated monetary values for each
of the n alternatives comprise the array of perceived benefits
for (B1,B2, . . . ,Bn) .
     In evaluating the choice among  treatment  alternatives,
the consumer weighs each alternative's monetized benefit, Bi,
against the cost of treatment, Ci-   The subjective  payoff from
each alternative can be expressed as
                              1-9

-------
                         nt =
     The consumer maximizes utility with respect to the
surface treatment choice by selecting the alternative with the
highest payoff.  This of course presumes that at least one of
the payoffs is not negative.  If all potential payoffs are
negative, the consumer is better off by choosing no surface
treatment at all.
     1.3.2.2  Substitution Effects .
     The purpose of this discussion is to describe how
consumption choices may change in response to any price
effects of the regulations.  If the regulations induce a
change in the price schedule of various architectural
coatings, the unit costs of treatment alternatives will be
directly affected.  Furthermore, the regulations may induce a
change in the structural characteristics of the coating that
alters the application technology.  For example, a different
VOC content may change the volume of the coating that must be
applied and the amount of labor and capital necessary to
achieve the same surface area treatment; consequently, the
technological parameters may change with the new VOC
requirements.  Therefore, treatment costs will be affected
jointly by what we call the factor price effect and the
technology effect.  If, for example, the VOC-content
regulations would raise the price of the affected coatings and
reduce the technological efficiency of the treatment process
 (e.g., more coats necessary), then both the factor price
effect and technology effect would combine to increase the
cost of the affected treatment alternatives, generating a new
set of treatment costs  {CV / • • . »Cn' ) .  Alternatively the new
formulas could improve technical efficiency, but at a higher
cost and the net effect on price would be unknown.
                              1-10

-------
     VOC-content regulations may also affect consumer
valuation of the treatment alternatives through a change in
visual characteristics and altered perceptions of quality or
durability.  These changes generate a new set of subjective
values for the treatment alternatives of  (B^ , . . . ,Bn') .  As a
result, evaluating the new arrays of benefits and costs
produces a new array of treatment payoffs,  (n^1...,nn' ) .  The
consumer can again be expected to select the treatment
alternative with the highest payoff.  This  situation may
produce a different optimal selection than  the no-regulation
case.  The consumer may in fact choose a noncoating
alternative or no-treatment alternative, where coating
treatment would be selected without the regulation.
     1.3.2.3  Aggregate Demand.
     If all consumers' preferences were identical and all
surfaces to be treated possessed the same characteristics, the
consumer choice model above would predict only one optimal
type of surface treatment throughout the economy.  A wide
array of treatments and coatings are actually applied,
however, indicating a variety of surfaces with different
characteristics as well as individual preferences that vary
across consumers.
     Aggregating over all consumers and all surfaces, we can
see how the regulatory changes can induce substitution among
treatment alternatives and changes in aggregate demand for the
affected coatings.  These aggregate changes in demand and the
associated effect on consumer welfare are the focus of this
study.
     1.3.2.4  Coating Users.   Users of coatings can be divided
into two groups:   professionals and nonprofessionals.  The
nonprofessional is typically a "do-it-yourselfer* who
purchases only a small amount of coatings each year.   The
application of coatings by nonprofessionals is limited
                             1-11

-------
primarily to residential  architectural coatings.  Professional
users of coatings may be  professional painters or contractor/
builders.  These professionals apply coatings to a broad array
of surfaces in residential,  commercial,  institutional, and
industrial settings.  Table  1-2 shows that in 1991
do-it-yourselfers purchased  two-thirds of all residential
architectural coatings.6  It seems reasonable to assume that
contractors purchased all of the nonresidential architectural
coatings and thus accounted  for 60  percent of the use of all
architectural coatings.

        TABLE 1-2.  CONSUMERS  OF ARCHITECTURAL COATINGS

                                   Percentage of Total
	Gallons in 1991 (%)	
 Residential
    Do-it-yourselfers                        41
    Contractors                               19
 Nonresidential"                             40
 Total                                      100
• Commercial,  institutional, light industrial.
Source: National Paint and Coatings Association.  U.S. Paint Industry Data
       Base.  Menlo Park, CA, SRI  International.  1992.

1.3.3  Production of Architectural  Coatings
      1.3.3.1  Raw Material  Inputs.   Coatings comprise  four
basic  types of materials:  pigment,  resin  (binder), solvent,
and  additives.   Pigment  is  the solid component consisting of
uniform particles of a controlled size that are insoluble in
the  vehicle  (the liquid portion of  the coating).  Pigments  are
used in coatings to decorate and protect and as fillers.7
Pigmentation, although it varies depending on desired
                              1-12

-------
properties,  is similar in both waterborne and solventborne
formulations.
     Film-forming binders surround and hold together the
elements of the coating film and make up the nonvolatile
portion of the vehicle.  Resins aid in adhesion; determine the
cohesiveness of the dried film; affect gloss; and provide
resistance to chemicals, water, and acids.  Natural and  .
synthetic resins and oils, along with certain additives such
as driers and plasticizers, serve as binders in coatings and
are one of three types:  multiuse resins  (acrylics, vinyls,
urethanes, polyesters); thermoset resins  (alkyds, epoxies);
and oils  (drying oils, bodied oils).
     The vehicles in organic solventborne and waterborne
paints differ not only by the type of resin used, but also in
the way they form a film and dry  (or cure).  Alkyd paints are
oxidizing film formers in which the drying oils react with the
oxygen in the air when the paint dries.  The chemical reaction
binds the molecules of the vehicle into a hard, dry film.
Alkyd coatings continue to oxidize long after they dry and
eventually provide a rock hard surface.  Latexes consist of
tiny, heat-sensitive plastic particles  (latex) that are
dispersed but not dissolved in water along with the pigment.
As the water evaporates, a layer of closely packed plastic
particles and pigment  is left behind.  The softened plastic
particles then lose their shape and molecules diffuse and
reattach  to form a binding film.8  The chemical
characteristics of latex and alkyd paint influence some of
their characteristics, such as gloss and resistance to
blocking  and water.  Heat-sensitive plasticizers in latex
paint cause the residual tackiness called blocking, which is
more of a problem in glossy latex paints where the ratio of
resin to pigment is higher.  Precise control of particle shape
and size  in the film former is necessary to increase gloss.
                              1-13

-------
The plastic mesh also breathes better, allowing water and air
to pass through it.  The oxidizing process of alkyds forms a
smooth  (thus glossier),  watertight skin of hardened resin that
provides durability and water resistance.
     Petroleum distillates in alkyd paints and water in latex
paint function as the carrier, or volatile vehicle, that
disperses the pigment and resin and provides the necessary
fluidity for applying the coating.  Basically there are two
types of solvents:  water and organic.  In alkyd paints
organic solvents dissolve the components of the film former,
keeping them in solution.  In latex paints, water separates
and suspends the droplets of film former.  Following
application, the evaporation rate of  the particular solvent
controls the rate at which the film forms, leaving the pigment
and resin bonded to the surface.  Latent solvents, which
dissolve the film former when combined with true solvents, and
diluents may be added to the true solvent.9  Diluents can be
blended with the dissolved solution to extend the true and
latent solvents.  Water is the true solvent used in latex
paints but may function as a diluent  in alkyd formulations.
Three types of organic solvents are used in coatings:
hydrocarbons (aliphatic, aromatic); oxygenated solvents
 (alcohols, esters, ketones, glycol ethers); and chlorinated
solvents  (1,1,1-trichloroethane, methyl chloroform).10
Architectural solventborne paints are mainly formulated with
aliphatic hydrocarbons.
     Additives are used in relatively small amounts in both
organic solventborne and waterborne formulations to provide
additional necessary properties or augment the properties of
other inputs.  They may be added to the film former, solvent,
or pigment.  Waterborne paints in particular may use additives
such as agents to reduce foaming or bubbling of paint when it
                              1-14

-------
is shaken and applied; wetting agents, which can improve
pigment dispersion or adhesion;  freeze-thaw agents, which
reduce the temperature at which  the paint will freeze to
prevent coagulation; and coalescing agents, which aid the flow
of the latex particles to form a more continuous film.11  VOC
contents in latex paints  (4 to 10 percent, or 50 to 200 g/L)
are due to the additives used.12  Solvents  such as alcohols  and
ethylene glycols are added as co-solvents to waterborne
formulations.  They are often necessary  to allow the plastic
particles to soften and be mobile enough to bind into a
continuous film.13
     The additives used in the largest volume are thickeners,
fungicides and preservatives, plasticizers, and defearners.14
Figures 1-2 and 1-3 show the principal raw material
ingredients discussed above as they are  used in organic
solventborne and waterborne coating formulations.
     1.3.3.2  Formulations.  One of the  distinguishing
characteristics of each coating  is the relative amount of the
three main material inputs contained in  the coating:  pigment,
binder, and solvent.  Different  formulations, particularly
different ratios of pigmentation in the  dried film to total
volume of the dried film  (pigment-volume concentration), will
lead to correspondingly different protective and decorative
functions.15  For example, a coating designed to hide surface
irregularities (like a mastic texture coating) has a higher
pigment-volume concentration than a gloss varnish whose
decorative function is to impart a shiny transparent or semi-
transparent coating.  Low pigment-volume concentrations have
an increased resin content and in general have high
durability, gloss, and washability.  The ratio of solvent to
nonvolatile components ("solids") also characterizes types of
                              1-15

-------
  Alkyd
  Resin
                             Aliphatic    Titanium
                           Hydrocarbons  Dioxide
Talc
 Nonvolatile        Volatile
 Component      Component    Hiding
(Film Former)        (Carrier)    Pigment         Extender
         Additives  /          \  Additives
                                          All Other Inputs
Figure  1-2.
                              Packaged Coating

     Inputs generally  used in the manufacture of  a
             solventborne coating.
        Aoyfc
        Retm
                    Water
                                       Titanium
                                       Dioxide
                    >lat*>     I
                    Nonvolatile      Volatile
                    Component     Component  Hidtfig
                   (Film Former)     (Carrier)    Figment
                         Additives
                                      Talc
                                     Extender
                                      AlOher Input*
Figure  1-3.
     Inputs generally used  in  the  manufacture  of  a
              waterborne  coating.
                        1-16

-------
coatings.d  Penetrating stains have a  low solids-to-solvent
ratio, and, when the  solvent  evaporates, virtually no film is
left behind.
     Figure 1-4 shows typical formulations and average VOC
contents for a few  architectural coatings.16  The coatings  in
Figure 1-4 with higher solvent content also have higher VOC
content.  A low solids-to-solvent ratio, as with
semi-transparent stain,  is associated with high VOC content in
coatings with organic solvents because VOCs are contained
almost exclusively  in the solvent portion of the coating.   Two
ways to reduce the  amount of  VOCs released from coatings are
to increase the solids-to-solvent ratio and to substitute
water for an organic  solvent.
     1.3.3.3  Manufacturers'  Substitution Options and New
Technologies.  Manufacturers  face two substitution
possibilities to reduce VOC emissions from coatings.  They may
reformulate the coating to increase the solids-to-solvent
ratio.  Alternatively,  manufacturers may reformulate the
coating so that it  contains the same amount of solvent but
emits fewer VOCs during application (i.e., substitute water
for an organic solvent).   Certain coatings such as interior
flat wall paint, interior semigloss,  and exterior house and
trim paint have been  formulated using water for several years.
Between 1950 and 1980,  waterborne coatings replaced
approximately 70 percent of solventborne coatings.17  The
performance of latex  paints often meets and even exceeds alkyd
counterparts; therefore,  manufacturers may choose to
discontinue organic solventborne paints in these product
classes.
     ^Nonvolatile components are often referred to as the "solids* portion
of the coating, which includes  pigments, resins, and  other additives,
although resins are not really  solid until the  film forms and are
considered part of the nonvolatile vehicle,  or  liquid portion of the
formulation.
                              1-17

-------
      Semitransparent
           Stain
  Exterior Nonflat
      Paint
General Primer or
  Undercoater
          Solvent


          Pigment
         Binder

     Solvent
     Pigment
                               Binder
1
    Solvent
                          Pigment
                                                     Binder
                                                          1
Average VOC Content

Organic solvent  527
Waterborne     85

    Figure 1-4.
                         Average VOC Content    Average VOC Content
Organic solvent
Waterborne
                                        76
      Organic solvent
      Waterborne
             48
                      Approximate  volume relationships of
                       coating ingredients.
Note:       VOC content in grains per liter from Table 1-1.

Source:     Whittington, Trevellyan V.  Paint Fundamentals.  In Paint
           Handbook.  Guy E.  Weismantel (ed.).  New York, McGraw-Hill.
           Pp. 1-1 to 1-23.  1981.   (Adapted from Figure 1.4)
     Other products,  including stains,  clears,  high-gloss

enamels,  outdoor varnishes,  and some special purpose coatings,

are more  difficult to reformulate.   According  to  a 1990

article,  clear coatings  have two problems associated with

them:   waterbornes are transparent  to UV radiation,  whereas

organic solventbornes absorb UV rays thus protecting the

substrate; and waterborne acrylic polymers are not strong

enough.18  Quality performance in  reformulated  products is

currently possible, but  the cost may be very high.19  As new

technologies become more refined, new resin systems, such as
                               1-18

-------
alkyd systems  once used only in solventbornes, will be  used  in
more coatings,  so  prices will become more competitive.
     High  solids content formulation is an alternative
technology to  waterborne formulations that manufacturers have
employed to reduce VOC emissions from coatings.  A high solids
coating is formulated with a high solids-to-solvent ratio."
Since a smaller percentage of solvent is contained in the
coating, fewer VOCs are released during application.
Table 1-3  shows example reduced solvent contents of three
different  types of reformulated organic solventborne
products.20
      TABLE 1-3.  PERCENTAGE OF SOLVENT IN CONVENTIONAL AND
           REFORMULATED ORGANIC SOLVENTBORNE  COATINGS
                       Conventional Solvent   Reformulated Solvent
        Product             Content  (%)           Content (%)
Interior semigloss
Clear coatings
Stains
60
55 - 62
72 - 85
47
35 - 37
30 - 35
Source: Bakke, Timothy 0.  Clean Air Paints.   Popular Science.  237:85.
       August 1990.
     Disadvantages  noted in the past of higher solids organic
solventborne paints include increased viscosity, longer drying
time, reduced durability,  and generally higher prices.21
Reformulated organic solventbornes may be thicker, which would
make them harder to apply and extend drying time, but they may
offer greater protection.   Durability may be compromised
because of the reduced  strength of shorter chain alkyd
molecules substituted for longer chain molecules to improve
flow.22  Reformulated alkyd products can offer some advantages
     •Note that the definition of high solids varies by coating type.
                              1-19

-------
however.  Durability may be traded for flexibility, which
provides increased resistance to cracking and peeling.
Presealers may not be necessary for wood substrates because
the thicker coatings penetrate more evenly.  Reduced VOC
emissions, lower odor, and reduced toxicity  and  flammability
are other benefits.
     Raw material suppliers are expanding and improving upon
existing technologies to meet demand for performance in new
waterborne and high solids formulations.  Solvents for use in
waterborne formulations  (i.e., glycol ethers) and high solids
(keytones, esters) are replacing many of the hydrocarbon
solvents used in solventborne formulations.  Resins are being
developed with a goal toward improved performance in new
low-VOC formulations; similarly additives are being developed
to improve flow and leveling characteristics of  the new
resins.  Additional low-VOC technologies are reactive diluent
technology, radiation curing technologies, and powder
coatings, which currently are mainly used in manufacturing
applications.
1.3.. 4  Industry Conditions
     1.3.4.1  Shipments and Manufacturer Specialization.  In
1991,  the architectural coatings segment of  the  paint and
allied products industry shipped $4,881.9 million in
potentially regulated products  (Table 1-4) .23.24.25,26.27,28,29,30,31,32
The value of shipments steadily increased by approximately
59 percent between 1981 and 1991, with a slight  decrease
between 1990 and 1991.  The strong construction  market
throughout the 1980s helped contribute to this growth, but the
industry as a whole was generally considered to  be maturing  in
the early 1990s.33   In 1991, the size  of  the  architectural
coatings component relative to the total coatings industry was
37.8 percent.  New products are important to the paint and
allied products industry, because growth for individual
                              1-20

-------
               TABLE  1-4.  VALUE SHIPPED  OF POTENTIALLY  REGULATED PAINT  AND  ALLIED PRODUCTS:
                                                     1981  THROUGH  1991  ($106)
1987
Product
Code
28511




28511 93
28511 00

28513

28513 0




28513 11
Product Class
Architectural coatings
Exterior solventborne
Exterior waterborne
Interior solventborne
Interior waterborne
Architectural lacquers
Architectural
coatings, n.s.k.*
Special purpose
coatings
Industrial new
construction and
maintenance paints
Interior
Exterior
Traffic marking paints

1991
4,881.
856.
1,166.
647.
2,054.
83.
73.






293.
503.
132.


y
8
0
2
8
3
7






8
2
4

1990
4,913.
890.
1,201.
644.
2,018.
85.
72.






265.
484.
138.


b
3
9
1
9
5
9






9
7
0

1989
4,525
819
1,062
655
1,850
73
63






240
497
138


.J
.7
.3
.1
.8
.5
.9






.0
.4
.0

1988
4,426
817
1,014
621
1,779
84
109






208
395
136


.8
.7
.3
.4
.2
.7
.6






.6
.2
,-i

1987
4,245
816
952
603.
1,620.
81
170.






179,
343
104


.4
.9
.7
.0
.1
.7
.9






.9
.1
6
Year
1986
4,010.0
765.3
899.8
553.5
1,491.9
81.2
218.2






128.7
321.8
78 5

1985
3,830
757
851
544
1,405
79
192






149
330
95


.8
.8
.1
.7
.5
.2
.4






.7
.2
9

1984
3,559,
731,
875,
512,
1,343,
64.
32,






126
252


.3
.0
.4
.6
.0
.9
.9






.9
.9
N/A

1983
3,320
672
833
490
1,210
57
35






103
191


.8
.4
.8
.2
.7
.6
.9






.5
.9
N/A

1982
3,092.2
621.9
789.1
473.1
1,119.7
45.3
42.9






120.0
209.7
N/A

1981
3,065.6
609.6
719.7
445.5
1,090.6
37.1
163.2






88.4
203.9
N/A
to  N/A  . Not available.
M  • n.s.k. » Not specified by  kind.
    Sources:  U.S.  Department of Commerce.
              Printing Office.   1983
              U.S.  Department of Commerce.
              Printing Office.   1984.
              U.S.  Department of Commerce.
              Printing Office.   1985.
              U.S.  Department of Commerce.
              Printing Office.   1986.
              U.S.  Department of Commerce.
              Printing Office.   1987.
              U.S.  Department of Commerce.   Current  Industrial Reports:
              Printing Office.   1988.
              U.S.  Department of Commerce.
              Printing Office.   1989.
              U.S.  Department of Commerce.   Current  Industrial Reports:
              Printing Office.   1990.
              U.S.  Department of Commerce.
              Printing Office.   1991.
              U.S.  Department of Commerce.
              Printing Office.   1992.
    Note:  Inflation factors used by the Census  to produce estimates for
           disaggregated figures here.  For  architectural coatings:  1987-
           purpose  coatings:  1987-1991,  1.06;  1982-1986, 1.00; and 1981,
           relationships and for 1982-1986  on 1982 Census relationships.
Current Industrial Reports:

Current Industrial Reports:

Current Industrial Reports:

Current Industrial Reports:

Current Industrial Reports:
Current Industrial  Reports:
Current Industrial  Reports:

Current Industrial  Reports:
Paints and

Paints and

Paints and

Paints and

Paints and

Paints and

Paints and

Paints and

Paints and

Paints and

the entire
1991,  1.00
 1.08. The
Allied Products,  1982.

Allied Products,  1983.

Allied Products,  1984.

Allied Products,  1985.

Allied Products,  1986.

Allied Products,  1987.
                        Washington,  DC,  Government

                        Washington,  DC,  Government

                        Washington,  DC,  Government

                        Washington,  DC,  Government

                        Washington,  DC,  Government

                        Washington,  DC,  Government

 Allied Products, 1988.  Washington,  DC,  Government

 Allied Products, 1989.  Washington,  DC,  Government

 Allied Products, 1990.  Washington,  DC,  Government

 Allied Products, 1991.  Washington,  DC,  Government

 industry  for aggregated data were applied  to the
; 1982-1986, 1.004; and 1981) 1.04.  For  special
 inflation factors for 1981 are based on  1977 Census

-------
producers is predicted to come from market share expansion,
new product introductions, and improvements in established
products.34
     Sales in the architectural sector generally reflect
activity in house redecoration, maintenance and repair, as
well as sales of existing homes, new home building, and, to a
lesser extent, commercial and industrial construction.  Among
interior and exterior architectural coatings, the waterborne
coatings market dominates the sector and experienced a larger
percentage increase in growth than did organic solventborne
coatings.  Interior waterbornes grew the most, 88.4 percent
from 1981 through 1991.  In 1991, 76 percent of interior
coatings and 57.6 percent of exterior coatings were
waterborne.  Partly in response to environmental regulations
aimed at the reduction of VOC emissions, the industry has
shifted from manufacturing conventional organic solventborne
paints in favor of paints with high solids-to-solvent ratios
and waterborne and solventless paints.35  However, much of  this
trend has also been driven by consumer demand.
     Although the historical Census data do not identify value
of shipments for paint products within the four product
classes, other sources indicated that the majority of interior
wall and exterior siding paint jobs use waterborne
products.36'37'38  Therefore, the exterior and interior solvent-
borne shares probably account for mainly coatings used on
exterior and interior trim, floors, decks, and high-gloss
enamels.
     Industrial new construction and maintenance paints and
traffic marking paints are classified by the Census as special
purpose coatings, which comprised 22 percent of the total
coatings market in 1991.  Market shares for industrial
maintenance and traffic marking paints within the special
purpose segment were 28 percent and 4.6 percent, respectively.
                              1-22

-------
Growth prospects for this segment  are expected to be above
average, especially for industrial and machinery maintenance
coatings.
     For all companies classified  in the paints and allied
products industry in 1987,  98 percent of their value of
shipments was generated from the manufacture of paints and
allied products  (Table 1-5).fi39  Only 3 percent of the value of
paints and allied products  shipped were manufactured by
companies outside the industry.  The top three secondary
producers of paint and allied products account for about half
the value produced as secondary products in other industries
and are shown in Table 1-6:  adhesives and sealants,  plastics
materials and resins, and printing ink.40  Because coating
products often function as  sealants,  the adhesives and
sealants industry is a logical secondary producing industry.
     1.3.4.2  Company Size  and Industry Structure.
Information on industry structure  is highly dependent on one's
definition of the industry  in question.   The data used in this
discussion apply to the entire Paint and Allied Products
Industry (SIC 2851).  As indicated above,  architectural
coatings account for just under 40 percent of industry
shipments.   Unfortunately,  the industry structure data are not
available for the architectural coatings component of the
industry.  Therefore, the information presented here may not
always accurately reflect the structure of the architectural
coatings sector.
     In 1987, the paint and allied products industry comprised
1,121 companies owning a total of  1,428 establishments
(Table 1-7) ,41-42  Single establishments were held by
approximately 77 percent of the companies,  and they had an
     £Industry statistics, unless otherwise noted,  include figures for all
segments of the paint and allied products  industry,  not just those to be
regulated.

                              1-23

-------
 TABLE  1-5.   NUMBER OF COMPANIES, ESTABLISHMENTS, AND PRODUCER
         SPECIALIZATION-PAINT AND ALLIED PRODUCTS:  1987
                                   Industry
                                         Primary
        Industry/             Number of     Product    Coverage
  SIC     Primary    Number of  Establish-  Specialization   Ratio
 Code   Product Class  Companies    ments     Ratio (%)*     (%)b
                                         Product
                                          Class
                                        Total Made
                                          in All
                                        Industries
 2851  Paints and
      allied
      products

 28511  Architectural
      coatings

 28513  Special
      purpose
	coatings	
1.123
1,426
           282
           131
98
97
12,078.8
•  Value of primary products for the industry divided by the sum of the value of
  primary products produced by the industry and the value of secondary products
  produced by the industry.

b  Value of primary products for the industry divided by the total value of
  products for that industry produced in any industry.

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce.  1987 Census of Manufactures, Industry Series:
       Paint and Allied Products.  Washington, DC,  Government Printing Office.
       1990.
average value  added of  $1.1 million.   The  multiestablishment

companies had  an average value added of  $20.4 million and

produced almost 85 percent of the total  value added for the

industry.  Also shown in Table 1-7,  the  50 largest  companies

in  1987 produced 66 percent of the total value of shipments

for the industry.   Data from the  Small Business Administration

(SBA)  indicate that in  1991 there were 1,152 companies and

approximately  98 percent of those were classified as small

businesses as  defined by having fewer than 500 employees.43

Figure 1-5 displays the location  of manufacturing

establishments in the paint and allied products industry by

state.44  California has the greatest number, 201,  followed  by

Illinois with  118.  Paint manufacturing  is fairly well

represented  in most states east of the Mississippi  River.
                                 1-24

-------
  TABLE  1-6.   COMMODITY PRODUCTION IN 1982:  PAINT AND ALLIED
                             PRODUCTS
       (SIC 2851)                              Value*    Percentage
    Product Examples	Producing Industries   ($106)	Produced

 Interior and exterior  Primary                8,243.3        96.5
 paint, lacquers, and
 varnishes; OEM         All secondary
 coatings; industrial     producers              303.2         3.5
 new construction and
 maintenance paints,     All producers          8,546.5        100.0
 traffic paints,
 automotive refinish
 paints, marine paints,  Top three secondary:     142.6         1.7
 aerosol coatings,         Adhesives and
 paint and varnish          sealants              68.8         0.8
 removers, thinners,       Plastics materials
 putty and glazing          and resins            45.8         0.5
 compounds, brush         Printing ink            28.0         0.3
 cleaners

                       All other secondary      160.6         1.9
                       producers

• Measured at producers' prices.

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce.   The 1982  Benchmark Input-Output
       Accounts of the United States. Washington, DC,  Government Printing
       Office.  1991.
     In  the  1980s,  consolidation was a major  trend in the

paint and  allied products industry.   The maturity of the

industry and increased technology requirements  are factors

contributing to the restructuring.   A large number of mergers

and acquisitions took place  in response to pressure from the

higher cost  of paint ingredients,  intense industry

competition,  compliance with government regulations,  and low

profit margins.45  Other companies divested  their paint and

coating  operations  to focus  on other businesses or as an

alternative  to making the capital and research  and development

(R&D) commitments required to remain competitive.   The number

of coating manufacturers and the number of establishments
                               1-25

-------
       TABLE 1-7.
LARGE FIRM DOMINANCE AND NUMBERS OF COMPANIES AND ESTABLISHMENTS
  IN  THE PAINT AND ALLIED  PRODUCTS  INDUSTRY:  1987
Industry
(SIC 2851)
Paint and allied
product producers
Multiestablishment
companies
Single-establishment
companies
Number of
Companies
1,121
259

862
j_, ' Percentages consist of the
• companies) , divided by the
to
Number of
Establish-
ments
1,428
566

862
Value
Added
6,220.7
5,271.3

949.3
Average
Value
Added"
(S106)
5.5
20.4

1.1
sum of value of shipments of
total value of shipments of
Value of Shipments
Percentage Accounted for
Total 4 Largest 8 Largest 20 Largest
($10') Companies Companies Companies
12,702.4 27 40 53
10,651.9

2,050.5
the four largest companies (or 8, 20,
the industry.

by •
50 Largest
Companies
66



or 50
b The total value added divided by the number of companies.

Sources:  U.S. Department  of Commerce.  Census of Manufactures,  Subject Series:  Type of Organization.
         Washington,  DC,  Government Printing Office, February 1991.

         Source for Percentage Accounted for Data:  U.S. Department of Commerce.  1987 Census of
         Manufactures,  Concentration Ratios of Manufacturers.   Washington, DC, Government Printing
         Office.  1992.

-------
I
to
                 Figure 1-5.   Location of  manufacturing  establishments in  the paints and

                                allied products industry  in 1987:  SIC 2851.
    Source:  U.S. Department of Commerce.  1987 Economic Censuses.  Volume 1, Report Series,  Release ID.

               Census of Manufactures:  Location of Manufacturing Plants.  file MC87LMCO.   1991.

-------
operated  by these manufacturers  has  decreased. As indicated  in
Table  1-8,  from 1972 to 1991,  the  number of companies
decreased by 12 percent, and  the number of manufacturing
establishments  decreased by over 20  percent.46
   TABLE 1-8.  NUMBER OF COMPANIES AND ESTABLISHMENTS IN THE
          COATINGS INDUSTRY,  SELECTED YEARS, 1972-1991
Year
1972
1977
1982
1987
1991
% change 1972-1991
Number of
Establishments
1,599
1,579
1,441
1,426
1,400.
-12.4%
Number of Companies
1,317
1,288
1,170
1,123
1,030'
-21.8%
• 1991 figures are from Finishers' Management.  The U.S. Paint and
  Coatings Industry,   pp. 23-25.  April 1991.
Source: U.S.  Department of Commerce.   1987 Census of Manufactures,
       Industry Series: Paints and Allied Products.  Washington,  DC,
       Government Printing Office.  1990.
      On average,  35 to 40 mergers  or acquisitions took place
each  year in the coatings industry in the late 1980s and  early
1990s.47  A transaction involves the transfer of production
capacity from one company to  another but does not necessarily
indicate the dissolution of the company making the transfer.
The selling company could sell  only a division or product line
and remain in business.  Some of the larger acquisitions
reported in trade journals, by  the press, and in companies'
annual reports are listed in  Table 1-9.*8
                               1-28

-------
TABLE  1-9.   ACQUISITIONS IN THE COATINGS  INDUSTRY:   CIRCA 1990
  Selling Company
  Acquiring Company
      Division Sold
 DeSoto
 Whittaker Corp.

 Azko  Coatings
   Inc.
 DeSoto
 Clorox  Co.
Sherwin Williams
Morton International

Reliance Universal
  Inc.
Valspar
PPG Industries, Inc.
Consumer Paint Operation
Specialty Chemicals
  Operation
Buyout
Coil Coatings Operation
Olympic and Lucite
  finishes
Source: Loesel, Andrew.  Coatings Industry Faces New Mix.  In Chemical
       Marketing Reporter.  238(18):SR3-SR8.  New York, Schnell Publishing
       Co.  1990.
     Most  of the larger companies produce architectural,
original equipment manufacturer (OEM),  and special purpose
coatings.   Several of the  largest coatings producers  are
chemical corporations; however,  paint manufacturing represents
only a  small part of their overall business.49   In 1991, merger
activity slowed down and left  the industry basically  divided
into two groups:  a few, well-financed and highly diversified
multinationals and a large number of regional paint
companies.
           50
                               1-29

-------
                           SECTION 2
    COSTS OF REGULATION FOR ARCHITECTURAL COATING PRODUCERS
     This section estimates the costs to comply with the
architectural coatings regulation and examines the economic
impacts of these costs as they are distributed across
producers and consumers of the regulated products through
market processes.  The analysis in this section focuses on
the(primary)impacts defined within the architectural coatings
product markets.  An assessment of impacts on users of traffic
coatings addresses selected secondary impacts in other sectors
of the economy.  That analysis is presented in Section 4.

2.1  BACKGROUND

     The EPA plans to control VOC emissions from architectural
coatings using a combined regulatory approach:  (1) product-
specific VOC content limits,  (2) an option for producers of
products that exceed the content limits to pay a fee on the
VOC content in excess of the limit, and (3) a phased tonnage
exemption that allows each manufacturer the option to claim as
exempt a limited number of products that result in a specified
amount of emissions annually.  Using reformulation cost
estimates and an exceedance fee rate, the Agency analyzed the
potential impacts of the regulation, first using static
analyses of regulatory response options and second using a
                              2-1

-------
dynamic market analysis that estimates changes in prices,
quantities, and social welfare.

2.2  OVERVIEW OF RESPONSE OPTIONS

     The regulation to reduce the VOC content of architectural
coatings will affect both production decisions for the
suppliers of the coatings (through its impact on costs and
revenues) and consumption decisions for the demanders  (through
its impact on product prices).   Before developing a formal
economic model to analyze these regulations, the Agency needed
to characterize the scope of responses available to producers
and consumers.
2.2.1  Supply
     The EPA is proposing a set of limits for the VOC content
in specific product categories to be met in 1999.  Firms that
produce products exceeding the VOC limits essentially have
three compliance options:

     •  reformulate  the products  so  that  they  comply with the
        standard,
     •  pay a fee  on the  excess VOC  content  over  the standard,
        or
     •  remove  the product  from the  market.

Each producer also may exempt a small quantity of product from
compliance.
     This analysis assumes that firms will choose the option
that maximizes their net benefits, as measured by the expected
 (discounted) value of the profits generated under each option.
Although decisions in the short-run may differ from decisions
made to maximize net benefits in the long run, this analysis
primarily considers the long-run decisions and their impact on
                              2-2

-------
the architectural coatings markets.  Uncertainties pertaining
to short-run decisions are discussed in Section 2.7.
     The first option for producers to comply with the rule is
to reformulate products that exceed the specified VOC content.
Product reformulation often involves an investment in research
and development  (R&D) to develop a compliant product.  The
extent of the reformulation necessary to bring a product into
compliance can vary from product to product.  In some cases,
compliance can be achieved for a particular product without
large R&D investments because the product is similar enough to
an existing formula or another product undergoing
reformulation.  A major reformulation, as is discussed
throughout this analysis, typically requires a significant
resource and time commitment.  The process can take several
years and is divided into a number of different stages.
Figure 2-1 identifies the basic reformulation stages for a
prototype architectural paint (other coatings such as
varnishes may have fewer stages).51  The firm may subsequently
need to alter its capital equipment to produce the
reformulated product, but these physical capital adjustments
are usually small compared to developing the intellectual
capital to devise the new formula.
     The analysis that follows assumes that manufacturers bear
the full cost of each reformulation.  Since the VOC content
limits in the rule reflect available resin technologies,  it is
likely that the costs associated with reformulation will at
least partially be shared by resin manufacturers/suppliers.
In that regard, the direct impacts on manufacturers will be
overstated in the analysis.  This and other potential upward
and downward biases in the cost estimation methodology are
addressed later in this section.
                              2-3

-------
Formulate a Whoa Paint
I
Conduct FteW T*tHno *nd Cotof Formutotfon



1
I
Formulate the Bases 1
(that wM be tinted) |
I
Determine Prescription for Raul
Stores
1
                             Develop Information
                         (technical and safety sheets, marketing
                        	Information, labels)	
                       Scale Up Production, Introduce, and Distribute
                        Estimated Effort     2 to 3 person-years
                        Estimated Elapsed Time: 1.5 to5.5 year*
  Figure 2-1.  Basic stages of architectural coating reformulation
                    (prototype  firm and product).
Source: AIM Coatings Regulatory Negotiation Committee meeting.
       July 28-30, 1993,  Washington, DC.  Meeting Summary.
2.2.2   Demand
     The regulation can be expected to  induce changes in the
prices  of the affected products.   Product  consumers  may alter
their selection of  coatings  based on the relative prices of
coating products  and on the  relative prices of coating versus
noncoating alternatives.  For  example,  consumers might opt for
a waterborne coating rather  than its solventborne alternative
if the  regulation-induced change in prices increases the
relative price of the solventborne product.  Moreover, a
potential user of a high-VOC coating product facing
reformulation may even opt for a noncoating alternative if the
price rises too much.
                                 2-4

-------
     The reformulated products  can also possess  different
characteristics  that affect  their demand.   For instance,  VOC
content reduction  in a  typically high-VOC  product may change
consumers' perceptions  of  the product's performance,
durability, and  ease of application.   The  lower  VOC content
may also work as a signaling device for the "green* consumer
in pursuit of products  deemed more friendly to the
environment.*  These factors collectively  affect  the benefit
consumers derive from using  the product and thus their
willingness to pay for  the reformulated product  versus other
product alternatives.

2.3  COST ANALYSIS

     This section  evaluates  the costs imposed on manufacturers
to reformulate noncompliant  products,  describes  and quantifies
the exceedance fee provision, and incorporates the option of
withdrawing products from  the market into  the decision
process.
2.3.1  Costs of  Reformulation
     Of the compliance  options  referenced  above,  reformulation
of products that have a VOC  content exceeding the category
limit in the TOS (see Table  2-1) is the most significant  both
in terms of potential cost and  emission reductions.  The
economic analysis  begins by  estimating the national cost  of
the regulation in  the absence of other compliance options
(fee, withdrawal)  and ignoring  market responses.   This will
provide an upper-bound  estimate for the true national costs of
the regulation.  The national estimate will be modified
(reduced) as the other  compliance options  and market behavior
are explicitly considered  below.
     •Some manufacturers currently produce zero-VOC-content coatings that
are marketed as "clean air* coatings.
                              2-5

-------
                 TABLE 2-1.   TABLE OF STANDARDS'
                                                VOC Content Limit
            Architectural Coating                      (g/L)
Antenna coatings                                       500
Antifouling coatings                                   450
Antigraffiti coatings                                  600
Bituminous coatings and mastics                        500
Bond breakers                                          600
Chalkboard resurfacers                                 450
Concrete curing compounds                              350
Concrete protective coatings                           400
Dry fog coatings                                       400
Extreme high-durability coatings                       800
Fire-retardant/resistive coatings
   Clear                                               850
   Opaque                                              450
Flat coatings, N.O.S.
   Exterior                                            250
   Interior                                            250
Floor coatings                                         400
Flow coatings                                          650
Form release compounds                                 450
Graphic arts coatings (sign paints)                     500
Heat reactive coatings                                 420
High-temperature coatings                              650
Impacted immersion coatings                            780
Industrial maintenance coatings                        450
Lacquers (including lacquer sanding sealers)            680
Magnesite cement coatings                              600
Mastic texture coatings                                300
Metallic pigmented coatings                            500
Multicolor coatings                                    580
Nonferrous ornamental metal lacquers                   870
                                                        (continued)
                                2-6

-------
           TABLE  2-1.  TABLE OF STANDARDS' (CONTINUED)
                                                  VOC Content Limit
	Architectural Coating	(g/L)	
 Nonflat coatings, N.O.S.
    Exterior                                             380
    Interior                                             380
 Nuclear power plant coatings                            450
 Pretreatment wash primers                               780
 Primers and undercoaters, N.O.S.                        350
 Quick dry coatings
    Enamels                                              450
    Primers,  sealers,  and undercoaters                   450
 Repair and maintenance thermoplastic coatings
                                                         650
 Roof coatings                                           250
 Rust preventive coatings                                400
 Sanding sealers                                         550
 Sealers                                                 400
 Shellacs
    Clear                                                650
    Opaque                                               550
 Stains
    Opaque                                               350
    Clear and semitransparent                            550
    Waterborne low solids                                120
 Swimming pool coatings                                  600
 Thermoplastic rubber coatings and mastics               550
 Traffic marking paints                                  150
 Varnishes                                               450
 Waterproofing sealers and treatments
    Clear                                                600
    Opaque                                               400
 Wood preservatives
    Below ground                                         550
    Clear and semitransparent                            550
    Opaque                                               350
N.O.S.  = Not otherwise specified.
*     The  final Table of Standards included in the regulation differs
      slightly from this list.   See Section 7 for a discussion.
                                 2-7

-------
     The method for estimating the national costs of the
regulation under this scenario is to:

     1.    Estimate reformulation cost per product
     2.    Estimate the total number of products nationwide
          facing reformulation
     3.    Multiply the cost per product times the number of
          reformulations

These steps are now presented in sequence.
     2.3.1.1  Product-Level Reformulation Cost Estimates.
     Developing a new formula for an architectural coating
involves altering the mix of the four coating components:
resins,  solvents, pigments, and additives.  For solventborne
products, a new formula might increase the ratio of solids
(resins) to solvents to reduce the solvent's contribution to
VOC emissions.
     Reformulation is a one-time investment to develop a
formula that complies with the VOC requirement.  This
generally involves applying R&D effort to develop and test the
new formula.  Various other expenses (e.g., administrative and
marketing) are incurred to get the reformulated product to
market;  however, for the purposes of this report, all relevant
costs are collectively referred to as "reformulation" costs.
     The level of effort for reformulation varies across
products, depending on the product's characteristics and the
difference between a product's VOC content and the standard.
For the analysis at proposal, EPA used information provided at
a regulatory negotiation meeting on July 28, 1993 on the cost
of developing a new product formula to meet a standard that
was more stringent than that which was proposed.52  Because
other data were not available to gauge the reasonableness of
this estimate,  the EPA solicited input during the public
comment period for this rule to determine the appropriateness
                              2-8

-------
of the value used  at proposal.   Appendix B provides a summary
of the information received.  These data show that the value
used at proposal was considerably above estimates provided by
commenters.  Thus,  the value used for this analysis is revised
to reflect both the initial estimate from the regulatory
negotiation and the subsequent estimates provided during the
public comment period.  Not enough information was provided in
these comments, however,  to estimate separate costs for each
specific product category;  therefore, the average of the
estimates provided is used as the cost of reformulation for
all products subject to the regulation.  That average cost is
$87,000 per product and will be used throughout this analysis
to estimate the economic impacts, unless otherwise indicated.15
     Cost annualization.   Several of the comments received
during the public  comment period indicate a  concern that the
cost estimate used at proposal was too low.   However,  the
lump-sum cost estimate used at proposal  ($250,000)  was
considerably higher than the estimates provided in the public
comments.  Therefore,  the concern appears to be centered
around the annualized cost estimate used at  proposal ($17,772
per year).  In many cases,  commenters appeared to be comparing
the annualized cost used in the proposal to  their estimate of
lump-sum costs to  reformulate.   The purpose  of annualizing
costs and the methods for doing so in this analysis are
presented below.
     Reformulation is a one-time effort to develop a new
formula.  But the  useful life of the formula goes beyond the
year in which reformulation occurs.  In this regard,  it is
     "Please note that because the base year for all information to
develop the regulation (i.e., product inventories, VOC content limits,
estimated emission reductions, etc.) is  1991, all costs and economic
impacts presented in the  analysis are expressed  in 1991 dollars unless
otherwise indicated.  All cost and economic impact measures are
transformed to present dollars in Section 7 for  external reporting
purposes.
                               2-9

-------
much like any other capital investment  (in this case,
"knowledge* capital), so the cost must be amortized over the
useful life of the investment.
     The standard formula for annualizing a lump sum
investment cost is

                a = I • [i(l+i)n / ((l+i)n -  1)]

where a equals the annualized amount, I is the initial lump
sum investment cost, i is the interest  (discount) rate, and n
is the useful life of the investment.  As indicated above, the
revised value for the lump-sum investment used throughout this
analysis is $87,000 per product.  The discount rate is
7 percent, which is the rate recommended by the Office of
Management and Budget  (OMB) for cost-benefit analysis of
federal regulations.53  Determining the  number of years to use
in the annualization formula, n, requires considering the
^useful life" of the knowledge developed in reformulation.
More specifically, how long do the benefits of the current
investment accrue?  Reformulation allows the firm to continue
to sell the current product  (at a lower VOC content), rather
than remove the product from the market.  Therefore, the time
stream of the benefits to the firm is at least as long as the
reformulated product will remain on the market (i.e., the
product life).  This is a complicated issue.  A particular
version (formula) of a product may remain on the market for
many years, then be reformulated to add different product
attributes and kept in the market as a new and improved
version of the old product.  This product reformulation
rotation may recur continuously into the future.   If so, what
is the best way to estimate the useful  life of the VOC
reduction technology induced by the regulation?
                             2-10

-------
     Two assumptions were considered to capture the range of
possibilities for the useful life of the reformulation
investment.

     1.    The low-VOC technology developed for the new formula
          is applicable only to that formula and cannot be
          transferred to future adjustments of the product.
     2.    The low-VOC technology developed for the new formula
          is applicable to that formula and is transferrable
          to all future versions of the product forever.
     Case 1:  In the first case, if the reformulated product
is expected to remain on the market for a certain number of
years (T),  then the useful life of the VOC reduction
investment is T years and the initial cost should be
annualized accordingly  (n=T).  Moreover, if the current
product  is simply replaced T years hence by a reformulated
version  of the product, it is assumed that the VOC reduction
technology developed for the current product is
nontransferrable to the next product.  Thus, an entirely new
investment in VOC reduction technology T years in the future
(the time of the next reformulation) is assumed necessary.
This defines the most pessimistic  (i.e., shortest) estimate
for the  useful life of  the current VOC reduction investment.
Because  shortening the  useful life of an investment reduces
the amortization period, it also raises the annualized cost of
compliance, therefore providing the upper-bound estimate for
this analysis.
     Estimating the cost under the first assumption requires
determining an appropriate product life for a typical
architectural product.  Attempts to obtain this information
from secondary data and industry sources proved unsuccessful
since a  "typical* product was too difficult to define.  A life
of T=8 years was assumed to be a reasonable, if conservative,
base case estimate of a single product life cycle.  Thus a^ is
                              2-11

-------
the annualized reformulation cost per product for case 1  (high
estimate), with an $87,000 reformulation investment, a useful
life of 8 years, and discounted at 7 percent, which is
computed as follows:

       at  = $87,000  [0.07(1.07)" / ( (1.07)8-1) ] = $14,573.

     Case 2:  In the second case, the low-VOC technology
developed for the regulation applies to all current and future
versions of the reformulated product.  In other words, once
the VOC technology is developed for the new formula, it does
not need to be re-developed in the future, even if the product
is modified in the future to add new attributes.  As a result,
the useful life is the length of time the firm expects to
remain in the product market.  In the extreme case, the firm
has no plans to remove the product from the market and the
useful life is essentially infinite.  Under this assumption,
the cost is amortized in perpetuity to make it comparable with
the benefits of the VOC technology.  Thus, the cost
annualization formula yields a2,  the estimate of reformulation
cost per product:

                 a2   = $87,000 • 0.07 = $6,090.

     Because a firm may not expect to remain in the market
forever and/or the current VOC reduction technology may not
transfer perfectly to all future versions of the current
product, the assumption for case 2 can be viewed as a
lower-bound estimate of annualized costs.
     However, under an alternative interpretation, the costs
may be lower still.  Suppose a company, in the absence of the
VOC standards, would routinely reformulate its product every
few years.  Then, the VOC regulation can be viewed not as
                              2-12

-------
forcing  firms  to reformulate the product;  rather,  it  forces
them to  reformulate  their  products sooner  than  they otherwise
would.   Thus,  the one-time cost to the firm is  the present
value of accelerating  the  series of costs  that  would  occur
(later)  without the  regulation.   This  cost will,  in general,
be less  than the lump-sum  cost  of reformulation referenced
above; therefore, the  annualized measures  would be lower as
well.  This is demonstrated by  numerical example  in
Appendix C.
     To  summarize, data  from the regulatory negotiation and
public comment periods were used to provide EPA's  best
estimate of the cost of  reformulation.  The average
reformulation cost estimate is  $87,000 per product.   This is a
one-time cost that must  be annualized  for  policy analysis.
The annualized cost  estimate depends on the assumption about
the new  formula's useful life.   Under  a useful  life estimate
of 8 years, the annualized cost  per product is  $14,573.  As
indicated, a number  of assumptions can be  justified on
theoretical and empirical  grounds that would reduce this
estimate.  For example,  the useful life of the  reformulation
investment may well  exceed 8 years.  Also,  reformulations
occur as a normal business practice and the cost of
reformulation for VOC  content may not  be entirely  incremental.
However, the $14,573 estimate is the maintained value
throughout the analysis, except  where  otherwise indicated,
thereby  providing a  conservatively high cost estimate.
     South Coast Air Quality Management District  (SCAQMD)
study.   As a point of  comparison,  estimates  of  the cost of
architectural coatings reformulation are provided  in a study
conducted for the SCAQMD to address  economic impacts of VOC
content  regulations  in California.54 This  study identified
costs associated with  product reformulation and temporary and
permanent product sales  losses.   Reformulation  costs varied
                              2-13

-------
depending on the extent of the reformulation necessary.  Most
of the small firms surveyed indicated that they did not have
full-time R&D employees.  Costs for additional research and
development due to the regulation ranged from $1,000 to $5,000
annually for firms with few products affected by the
California rule and more than $50,000 for firms with many
affected products and little or no research staff.
     The SCAQMD study also identified other compliance costs
not related to R&D.  Rough estimates of the cost of equipment
adjustments necessary to accommodate reformulation ranged from
$5,000 to $35,000 per firm.  Costs attributed to temporarily
or permanently discontinued products ranged from zero to
$3,000 for firms with few affected products to more than
$75,000 for firms with many affected products.  Per-product
estimates were not presented.  Employment changes for the
surveyed firms in the SCAQMD study were expected to be
minimal, affecting only the possible addition of R&D chemists.
     Because the timing, number of reformulated products, cost
components, and regulatory structure associated with each
SCAQMD cost estimate are not apparent from the report, they
cannot be combined with the estimates presented above in any
meaningful fashion to improve the estimate of regulatory
costs.
     2.3.1.2  National Reformulation Costs.  The analysis of
national reformulation costs begins with the recognition that
the population of regulated products can be broken into two
groups:  those included in the emissions survey and those
omitted from the survey.  The methods used to estimate costs
for each group are presented in turn.
     Survey population.  In this section, aggregate
reformulation costs are for the products reported in the
Architectural and Industrial Maintenance Surface Coatings VOC
Emissions Inventory Survey (the survey).55  The survey
                              2-14

-------
population represents roughly three-fourths of total industry
output. The analysis is then extended to the industry level to
calculate a national estimate.
     To estimate reformulation costs for the entire survey
population, the number of architectural products that will
need reformulation to comply with the standards is determined.
This number depends on the number of architectural products
with a VOC content exceeding the standards for the respective
product categories.
     The survey reports the number of products, sales volume,
and average VOC content for specific VOC content ranges  (e.g.,
0 to 50 g/L, 51 to 100 g/L, 101 to 150 g/L) within specific
product groups (e.g., exterior flat waterborne, exterior flat
solventborne, interior flat waterborne).  Knowing the limits
imposed by the TOS,  the number, volume, and average VOC
content of products over the limit can be derived using the
survey data.  These data can be used to generate estimates of
the expected cost of reformulating products subject to the
TOS, as well as the associated reduction in emissions
accomplished by the reformulations.
     Nonsurvey population.  By definition, characterizing the
population of nonsurveyed products introduces further
uncertainty into the analysis.  To estimate the number of
nonsurveyed products facing reformulation, one must use
product information from the survey population and apply it to
the nonsurvey population subject to some assumption about the
correspondence between the two populations.  The economic
analysis presented at proposal performed this task subject to
the assumption that the overall survey population was
representative of the nonsurvey population.  Further scrutiny
suggested a more appropriate assumption would be that the
nonsurvey population was more accurately represented by the
small company component of the survey population.   A
                             2-15

-------
supplemental analysis in the appendix of the proposal analysis
addressed this issue and indicated that national cost of the
regulation is higher when the assumption that all nonsurveyed
products are produced by small companies is applied.  That
assumption is maintained and further refined to generate cost
estimates for the nonsurvey population in this analysis, as
described below.
     For each of the 13 defined market segments in the
architectural coatings industry, data were available on total
market volume (in liters) derived from the Census of
Manufactures data for the baseline year (1991) and the total
volume of surveyed products for that category.  From that data
the total volume omitted from the survey (i.e., volume
produced by the nonsurvey population) can be computed:

     Nonsurveyed volume = Market volume - Surveyed volume (2.1)

If the average size of nonsurveyed products is known, the
number of nonsurveyed products can be estimated as follows:

Nonsurveyed products  =  Nonsurveyed Volume / Average
                         volume of an nonsurveyed product (2.2)

If the proportion of nonsurveyed products needing
reformulation is known, then the number of nonsurveyed product
reformulations can be computed:

Nonsurveyed product reformulations =
          Nonsurveyed products • Proportion of
          nonsurveyed products needing reformulation      (2.3)

and the corresponding reformulation costs are then
                             2-16

-------
Cost of nonsurveyed product reformulations =
          Nonsurveyed product reformulations •
          Reformulation cost per product                  (2.4)

Because no specific data on nonsurveyed products were
available for this analysis, the average product volume needed
in Eq. (2.2) and the reformulated product proportions needed
in Eq. (2.3) are not known.  However, the information from the
surveyed products can be used to impute values for the
nonsurveyed products.  One option is to assume that
nonsurveyed products are the same average size and have the
same rate of product reformulation as surveyed products.
However,  as indicated above, the survey population is not
necessarily representative of the nonsurvey population,
because the former includes mostly large companies and the
latter mostly small companies.  To more appropriately capture
the differences between the nonsurvey population and the
survey population, the following assumptions are proposed:

      (1)   Let the average size of nonsurveyed products in each
          market segment equal the average size of small
          company products reported for that market segment in
          the survey data.
      (2)   Let the nonsurveyed product reformulation rate in
          each market segment equal the reformulation rate for
          small company products reported for that market
          segment in the survey data.
The effect of assumption  (1) is to increase the number of
nonsurveyed products and thereby increase the number of
nonsurveyed product reformulations and associated costs,
relative to the alternative assumption that nonsurveyed
products are produced by both large and small companies.
Assumption  (2) adjusts the estimates based on market segment-
specific reformulation rates, which is greater on average for
small companies.  The combined effect of these two assumptions
                             2-17

-------
is to raise the cost of the regulation relative to the
alternative assumption.
     National estimate.  Typically during the development of
an air pollution regulation, an engineering analysis
identifies the pollution control equipment required to comply
with the rule and estimates the total installed capital cost
in a memorandum to the public docket or as a section of the
rule's Background Information Document (BID).  The economic
analysis typically uses this information to amortize costs on
an annual basis and perform a market analysis.  For the
architectural rule, the control cost estimates are highly
dependent on decisions made by the regulated producers in a
market setting to either reformulate, pay an exceedance fee,
or remove the over-limit product from the market.  With the
market emphasis, all costs were expressed in annual terms in
the economic analysis presented at proposal.  EPA received
public comments suggesting that an estimate of total initial
reformulation cost (the analog to total installed capital
cost) would also be informative.  This cost is computed and
presented below, along with the standard annual cost
estimates.
     The national reformulation costs can then be estimated as
follows:

     National reformulation cost =
          Cost of surveyed product reformulations +
          Cost of nonsurveyed product reformulations      (2.5)
     Table 2-2 presents the results of the analysis for the
TOS.56  The first row of Table 2-2 reports reformulation costs
and emissions reduction summed across all surveyed products.
A total of 1,730 products from the survey exceed the limits
that manufacturers and importers will be subject to, which is
36 percent of the total number of products in the survey
                             2-18

-------
                           TABLE 2-2.   NATIONAL COSTS:   REFORMULATION-ONLY SCENARIO
to
 i
M
VO
Annualized Cost of


Population
Surveyed
products
Nonsurveyed
products
Total

Number of Products
Over Limit
1,730

1,759

3,519

Estimated
Reformulations*
1,153

1,193

2,345

Initial Lump-Sum Cost -
($1991)
$100,282,029

$103,760,202

$204,042,231
Reformulation ($1991)

Low*
$7,019,742

$7,263,214

$14,282,956

High*
$16,797,240

$17,379,834

$34,177,074
Totals subject  to rounding error.
NA = not applicable
•  Based on the assumption that one-third of products over  the  limit do not need a major  reformulation (see
text).
6  Based on an initial investment of $87,000 cost per product.
c  Based on an annual!zed value of $6,090 cost per product.
d  Based on an annual!zed value of $14,573 cost per product.

Source:  Industry  Insights.  Architectural  and Industrial Maintenance Surface Coatings VOC Emissions Inventory
         Survey.   Prepared for the National Paint  and Coatings Association in cooperation with the AIM
         Regulatory  Negotiation Industry Caucus.   Final Draft Report.  1993.

-------
(4,846).c  A presentation to  the  Regulatory Negotiation
Committee  indicated that  roughly one in three products that
exceeds  the  limits  would  not need a reformulation, primarily
because  the  product lines are similar to others that will be
reformulated.   Thus,  the  costs are assessed for the remaining
two-thirds of products  over the  limit to compute the
aggregate  cost  estimate.   After reducing the number of
products,  the estimated number of reformulations for the
survey population is 1,153,  yielding a range for an aggregate
cost of  reformulation of  $7.0 to $16.8 million dollars (1991
dollars),  depending on  which useful life assumption is used to
annualize  the lump-sum  value.
     Nationally, about  2,345 products are subject to
reformulation.  The initial lump-sum cost to reformulate these
products (at $87,000 per  product) is just over $200 million.
Depending  on the annualized cost per product estimate used,
annualized costs range  from about $14 to $34 million per year.
Again, these estimates  overstate the expected cost of the
regulation because  they do not account for producers' best
response (i.e., their lowest cost option) to the regulation.
The next section discusses the part of the analysis that
accounts for these  actions.
2.3.2  Exceedance Fee Provision
     Architectural  coatings producers have the alternative of
paying a fee per unit of  output for products that exceed the
limit.   The  fee will be computed as follows:

       fee = (actual VOC content  - VOC  limit) • fee rate.  (2.6)
     °The actual survey total number of products is 4,920.  However,
throughout Section  2 of this report 4,846 is used as the total number (and
the corresponding quantity and emissions) because product-level data were
unavailable for 74  products in the survey.
                              2-20

-------
VOC content is measured in grams per liter  (less water and
exempt compounds) , and the fee rate is paid on the grams per
liter in excess of the limit.  The fee rate is $0.0024 per
excess gram per liter with annual adjustments based on the
gross domestic product (GDP) price deflator.  Total fee
payment per product simply equals the per-liter fee times
total liters of production.
     In this step of the analysis, the premise is that
architectural coatings producers will choose the less costly
of the reformulation and exceedance fee options as a
compliance strategy.  The choice is based largely on two
product-specific  factors:  quantity of output produced and the
"excess* VOC per unit.
     The diagram  in Figure 2-2 helps explain the effect that
output quantity has on the choice between reformulating the
product and paying an exceedance fee.  The vertical axis
represents the cost per liter of compliance and the horizontal
axis measures product volume in liters annually.  Since the
cost of reformulation is a fixed cost (i.e., it is independent
of the level of output),  the average reformulation cost per
liter of output falls as output levels increase.  This
situation is represented by the downward-sloping line in
Figure 2-2.  However, the exceedance fee per unit of output is
constant with respect to the output levels.  Let F be the
exceedance fee per liter of output; the flat line extending
from F on the vertical axis indicates that the fee rate is
constant.  For the purposes of this discussion,  we ignore the
role of fixed recordkeeping costs under the fee option.  These
costs are included in the empirical analysis that follows.  In
Figure 2-2, for all output levels less than QT the average
cost of reformulation is higher than the per-unit fee,  and for
all output levels greater than QT,  the  average cost  is  below
                             2-21

-------
          S/liter
                                        Av«ng« Co»t of
                                        Reformulation
                         QT
Output L*v«l
                 Favors Fee        Favors Reformulation
             Figure 2-2.   Fee versus reformulation.

the fee.  This relationship  indicates  that the fee is the less
costly alternative when output  is  less than QT and
reformulation is the   less costly  alternative when output is
greater than QT.   Thus small volume producers  are more likely
to choose the fee, all else  equal.   As Figure 2-2 illustrates,
the existence of a fee places an upper limit on the per-liter
costs of complying with the  regulation:   F • Q.
     Figure 2-2 also  illustrates the effect of different fee
rates on the "threshold point*  of  quantity, below which the
fee is the preferred  option.  If the fee were F' instead of F,
reflecting either a higher assessment  rate per Mg of emissions
or a higher amount of excess VOC per unit, the threshold point
would be lower.  Thus, for higher  excess VOC categories and
for higher fee rates,  fewer  producers  would probably select
the fee option, all else  equal.  Because the fee will be more
cost-effective only for lower-volume products and lower
                              2-22

-------
excess-VOC categories, allowing the fee option should have a
relatively small impact on variation from the aggregate
emission reduction targets as long as the fee assessment rate
is not set at an extremely low level.
2.3.3  Product Withdrawal
     Up to this point, the analysis has focused on firms
responding to the regulation by choosing the less costly
alternative between reformulation and the fee regulatory
response.  However, this view of a producer's likely response
is incomplete because the cost of the regulatory response must
be weighed against the benefits of the action to the firm.
Here the analysis equates regulatory compliance with the
decision to pay the costs and remain in the market.  Thus, the
benefits of the compliance action are the net returns
(revenues minus variable costs) obtained from continuing to
produce the product.  The net payoff of compliance for a
particular architectural coating exceeding the limit can be
expressed as follows:

                    nR = P • q  - c(q) - r*.                (2.1)

To ease the notational burden,  all terms are expressed in
their annualized form:  P is product price,  q is annual
output, c(q) is the product cost function (without regulation)
with respect to annual output,  and r* is the annualized cost
of the least-cost option among regulatory responses (i.e.,
reformulation or fee).  In other words,  r* gives the cost of
the solution to the least-cost decision discussed in the
previous section.
     The firm is assumed to select an output level (q*) that
maximizes profits (nR*) .  In a competitive market, this is the
point at which the marginal cost of production equals the
market price.   However,  the firm will only operate in this
                             2-23

-------
market if it can cover its production costs and compliance
costs; that is, if the following condition is met:

                        nR* (q** r*) * 0.                   (2.8)

If the condition in Eq.  (2.8) is not met, then the firm's best
response is to withdraw the product, produce no output  (q?'=Q),
and generate zero profits for the product (nR*=0) .  In  this
regard, product withdrawal would be the firm's least cost
option, because the alternative implies they lose money by
remaining in the market.
2.3.4  "Best-Response* Analysis
     The analysis presented here determines which option  (fee,
reformulation, or withdrawal) is the best response for
specific products within a certain VOC content range from the
survey.
     For the purpose of this analysis, a product stratum is
defined as all products existing in a specific VOC content
range  for a specific product category.  An example of a
stratum would be all exterior flat waterborne products in the
101 to 150 g/L VOC content range.  For the TOS, all strata in
the survey were examined to determine those that exceed limits
for their respective product categories.  As indicated above,
the survey includes data on the number of products, sales
volume, and baseline VOC emissions for each stratum.  These
data were used to compute average sales volume per product for
all strata exceeding the TOS limits.  These average volume
estimates formed the basis for computing exceedance fee costs
and product-level profits.
     An example of a best response determination is as
follows:
                              2-24

-------
           (Best-Response Example)
           Suppose the average sales  volume per product  for one
     stratum  is  100,000 L/yr.  To  determine the exceedance fee
     for each stratum, the midpoint  of the VOC content  range
     was used as an estimate of average VOC for the  stratum.
     This  measure was used to compute excess VOC content
     because  it  is consistent with the regulatory definition
     of VOC content (grams per liter less water and  exempt
     compounds)  and is available for each stratum.
           First  the fee rate was adjusted to 1991 dollars by
     multiplying the fee rate  (in  1996 dollars) of 0.0028/g by
     the ratio 1991/1996 of GDP price deflators.  The
     resulting fee rate is 0.0024/g.   Suppose the midpoint of
     the stratum is 150 g/L above  the limit.  The associated
     fee per  unit would be 150 • $0.0024  = $0.36/L.   The  total
     exceedance  fee payment for the  product is
     ($0.36/liter) • 100,000 liters =  $36,000 per year.   Fixed
     recordkeeping costs must also be incurred for products
     subject  to  the fee.  Fee-related  recordkeeping costs
     were  estimated to be $590 per product per year.57   Adding
     these numbers together, the compliance cost under  the fee
     option is $36,590 per year.   This exceeds the annualized
     cost  of  reformulation  ($14,570  per year).  Under these
     conditions, it is assumed that  products in this stratum
     would reformulate rather than pay the exceedance fee.d
     This  decision would be reversed if,  for instance,  the
     stratum  exceedance were 50 g/L,  in which case the  fee
     "By conducting the fee-versus-reformulation decision at the stratum
level, and  basing the decision on average cost and  fee for each stratum,  it
is implied  that all products within the stratum are identical to the mean
values.  In reality, there will be some variation around the mean so that
some producers may find one alternative less costly while others find the
other alternative less costly.  This analysis is unable to capture this
heterogeneity with the available data, but presumably these effects are
smoothed out as the analysis compares means across  the hundreds of strata
in the survey.
                              2-25

-------
     payments would be $12,000, which, adding in the fixed
     cost of $590, is below the reformulation cost per
     product.
     To simulate the reformulation/fee/withdrawal decision,
per-unit profits were estimated to compare with unit costs for
each stratum and computed as follows:
                                                          (2.9)
where P is the output price and m is the profit margin.  For
each product category analyzed, the average market price for
the market in which the product category belongs was used  (see
Table 2-3) .58-59  The model derives the returns-to-f ixed-factors
(RFF) profit margin as follows:

               m = 1 - (variable cost/revenues).          (2.10)

The ratio of variable cost to revenue can be computed using
values provided by the NPCA.  The variable cost component in
the numerator includes the cost of goods sold plus variable
selling and storage costs.  These variable costs comprise
81.7 percent of revenues for the mean producer surveyed by
NPCA, so the estimate of the RFF profit margin is 0.183.
     These average reformulation cost per liter and profit
calculations were performed for each stratum above the TOS
limits to determine the relative frequency of reformulation/
fee/withdrawal selections and their impact on compliance
costs.  These analyses were performed directly for the survey
population,  with the results used to impute values for the
nonsurvey population.  Results are presented for the survey
population in Table 2-4.
     Under the chosen fee rate of $0.0024 (1991 dollars), the
fee is the preferred alternative for 409 (35.5 percent) of the
                             2-26

-------
  TABLE  2-3
ARCHITECTURAL  COATINGS MARKET SEGMENTS  BASELINE
             DATA FOR  1991

No.
1

2

3

4
5

6

7

8

9
10
11
12
13



Market Segment4
Exterior & high performance
solventborne coatings
Exterior & high performance
waterborne coatings
Interior solventborne
coatings
Interior waterborne coatings
Solventborne primers &
undercoaters
Waterborne primers &
undercoaters
Solventborne clear coatings,
sealers, & stains
Waterborne clear coatings &
stains
Architectural lacquers
Wood preservativesc
Traffic marking paints
Special purpose coatings
Industrial maintenance
coatings
Totals /averages
Quantity
Produced (kL)b
162,937

468,345

94,935

833,434
61,298

75,212

134,678

120,738

40,011
27,449
91,067
34,568
231,261

2,375,933

Value ($103)
540,511

1,046,383

302,264

1,747,341
171,583

160,960

412,743

266,174

83,320
493,965
132,358
141,633
797,006

6,296,241
Average
Price
($/L)
3.32

2.23

3.18

2.10
2.80

2.14

3.06

2.20

2.08
1.45
1.45
4.10
3.45

2.65
•  See Appendix A for an explanation of  products  included in each market
  segment.

b  The quantities and values are taken from Census data except the quantity
  for wood preservatives, which is taken from the survey.

c  For wood preservatives the quantity is taken from the survey,  but the
  price is taken from the Census data.

Sources:  U.S.  Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial  Reports:  Paints
          and Allied Products,  1991.  Washington, DC,  Government  Printing
          Office.   1992.

          Industry  Insights.  Architectural and Industrial  Maintenance
          Surface Coatings VOC  Emissions Inventory Survey.   Prepared for
          the National  Paint and Coatings Association in cooperation with
          the AIM Regulatory Negotiation Industry Caucus.   Final  Draft
          Report.   1993.
                                   2-27

-------
    TABLE 2-4.
BEST-RESPONSE OPTION ANALYSIS-SURVEY  POPULATION:
                             ($1991)
FEE  = $2,200/TON
Number'
of Products
Above the
Limit
Reformulation
selected
Fee selected
Withdrawal
selected
Total
697
409
46
1,153
Product
Quantity (L)
239,
38,

278,
183
235
772
191
,643
,442
,807
,893
j^j • Total products over-limit times (2/3)
I b If fee not selected, reformulation costs
£j? withdrawal is not selected, reformulation
Reformulation
Cost
$10,160,142
$0
$0
$10,160,142
Fee
Payments
$0
$3,225,366
$0
$3,225,366
for the 409 products that
costs for the 46 products
Foregone
Profits
$0
$0
$415,178
$415,178
Total
Costs
$10,160,
$3,225,
$415,
$13,800,
Cost Savings
from Not
Reformulating6
142
366 $2,738,
178 $255,
686 $2,993,
$0
616
042
658
selected the fee are $5,963,982. If
that selected withdrawal are $670,220.
Source:  Industry Insights.  Architectural and Industrial Maintenance Surface Coatings VOC Emissions Inventory
        Survey.   Prepared for  the National Paint and Coatings Association in cooperation with the AIM
        Regulatory Negotiation Industry Caucus.   Final Draft Report.  1993.

-------
1,153 products facing  the  reformulation versus fee decision."
However, these products  only account for 38 million liters of
output, about 14 percent of  the volume subject to the
decision, reinforcing  the  notion that the fee is selected for
lower-volume products.   The  total fee payment for those
products is about  $3.7 million (average is $0.08/L),  but the
estimated avoided  reformulation cost for the 409 products
choosing the fee is  over $5.9 million for a net aggregate
savings to producers of  about $2.7 million.  Moreover, because
the fee payment is simply  a  transfer from one sector of
society  (architectural coatings producers) to another (the
government), the social  cost savings due to incorporating the
fee are the full $5.96 million reformulation cost savings,
less any costs of  administering the fee.
     Table 2-4 indicates that 46 products elect withdrawal as
the best response  strategy to the regulation, which is less
than 0.1 percent of  the  4,846 products surveyed.  The
estimated foregone profits for those products total
approximately $415,000,  which should be considered a component
of "compliance cost" of  the  regulation.  However, this
produces a $255,000  savings  to society over the reformulation-
only option.
     All told, allowing  for  options other than reformulation
substantially reduces  compliance costs for the survey
population.  The option  to pay the fee or to withdraw reduces
the compliance cost  estimate by about $3.0 million, or about
18 percent of the  costs  that would be incurred by the survey
population if reformulation  were the only compliance option.
     •Note that 1,153 products represent two-thirds of the total number
exceeding the limits because the other one-third were assumed to
reformulate without incurring the "major* reformulation cost.
                              2-29

-------
2.3.5  Tonnage Exemption
     All producers will be allowed to exempt the following
quantity of VOC emissions from control that is phased in over
three years:

     Period 1:  23 Mg (25 tons)
     Period 2:  18 Mg (20 tons)
     Period 3:   9 Mg (10 tons)

Because these represent relatively small volumes,  especially
after the 3-year phase-in, the tonnage exemption will likely
serve in lieu of the exceedance fee for small volume products
and thereby reduce fee payments by producers employing the
tonnage exemption.
     To the extent that the tonnage exemption replaces the fee
as a compliance option for some products, the foregone fee
payments represent the reduced impact on producers.  Consider
the post-year 3 case where 9 Mg of VOC emissions are exempted
from control.  Suppose that 3.6 Mg of these emissions are
"exceedance" emissions  (i.e.,  emissions above the amount
allowed in the VOC content standards).  If a fee were assessed
to these emissions, the cost to the firm would be 3.6 •  $2,200
= $7,920 ($1991).  Therefore,  the exemption allows the firm to
avoid this impact.  Note that while this reduces the private
impact on firms subject to the exemption/fee, there is no
corresponding effect on the social cost of the regulation as
the reduced fee payments are just reduced transfers from one
party  (producers) to another party (government).

2.4  COST ANALYSIS UNCERTAINTIES

     Table 2-5 lists the key assumptions and main areas of
uncertainty surrounding the cost estimates.  Items of
                              2-30

-------
    TABLE 2-5.  REFORMULATION COST ANALYSIS UNCERTAINTIES
Assumptions

   •   Initial reformulation cost is $87,000.
   •   Useful life of reformulation is  (1) 8 years,  (2)  forever.
   •   Discount rate is 7 percent.

Potential upward bias factors

   •   Effects of tonnage exemption not considered.
   •   Costs assumed constant  in the future; but may  fall over  time
      as  new technology is developed and disseminated.
   •   Industry trends since 1991 have moved toward lower VOC
      formulations.
   •   Costs may be borne partly by material suppliers.
   •   Regulatory baseline is  changing.  State regulations have
      been implemented  (e.g., Massachusetts), and some producers
      have already developed  formulations and incurred
      reformulation costs to  comply with new as well as existing
      regulations.  These formulas can be applied to a  federal
      rule at a minimal cost.

Potential downward bias factors

   •   Costs are confined to the reformulated product itself; users
      may incur additional costs to adapt application systems.
   •   Multiple products may be lumped together as one in the
      survey.  Therefore,  multiple reformulations may be necessary
      in  some cases where a single reformulation is  projected.

Potential factors with unknown directional effects

   •   Estimate is for a "typical* product; individual products may
      differ.
   •   Lower-bound estimate of 8 years for useful life of
      reformulation is speculative.
   •   Reformulation may positively or negatively affect variable
      production costs  (e.g., materials).
   •   Effects on product quality and performance are unknown;
      anecdotal evidence shows both positive and negative effects
      depending on the product.
   •   Costs may rise/fall based on amount of "excess VOC" to
      reduce.
   •   The number of reformulations for nonsurveyed products may be
      mis-estimated due to lack of data.
                               2-31

-------
uncertainties are grouped by the likely direction of bias on
the cost estimate:  upward,  downward,  or unknown.
2.4.1  Upward Bias
     As indicated in the previous section,  one source of
upward bias in the cost estimates is that the analysis does
not directly account for the effect that the tonnage exemption
would have on cost mitigation.
     The analysis may overstate reformulation costs incurred
by architectural producers by not explicitly accounting for
cost-saving technological innovation.   Spillover effects from
early reformulation efforts could substantially reduce the
costs for other formulas.  This may be facilitated by the role
that material suppliers play in developing formulas,
particularly in the case of smaller architectural coatings
manufacturers.  Economies of scale may occur because material
suppliers solve the problem for multiple clients and formulas.
     Since this rule was initially proposed,  for example,
Massachusetts has implemented its own regulation for
architectural coatings.  In compliance with that regulation,
104 companies have registered compliant architectural coatings
with the Massachusetts Department of Environmental
Protection.60  Many of those companies operate on a national
scale.  Therefore, products those companies make that
currently meet the Massachusetts regulation do not need to be
further reformulated to comply with the national rule.  Those
costs are not "backed-out* in this analysis,  which imparts an
upward bias of unknown magnitude on the costs presented.
2.4.2  Downward Bias
     A couple of factors may lead to an understatement of the
reformulation costs presented here.  First, by focusing on
costs to the coatings manufacturer, the current analysis does
not account for any fixed costs that coating users may bear as
they switch to compliant formulas.  Based on public comments,
                             2-32

-------
the item of greatest concern in this category  is application
equipment for traffic marking coatings.  These costs are now
explicitly addressed in a separate section of  this report and
included in the final cost-effectiveness analysis below.
     The second item that may cause downward bias in the cost
estimates relates to the definition of products in the survey
data.  The analysis treats each survey entry as a separate
product and assigns each noncompliant entry a  single
reformulation.  If, instead, survey respondents combined
several products requiring several reformulations into one
survey entry, total reformulation costs for the survey
population would be underestimated.  It is impossible to
determine whether this is a systematic problem with the survey
data and, if so, the extent to which it biases the current
estimate.
     While the reformulation cost estimate is  the main source
of uncertainty in the analysis, another item that bears
mentioning relates to the selection of nonreformulation
response options (fee or withdrawal).  The analysis assumes
that producers will select the lower-cost option
(reformulation or the fee) and exit if the lower-cost option
exceeds the value of the profit stream.  However,  some
rigidities (e.g.,  shortage of scientist hours  for new formula
development)  might make reformulation difficult in the very
short run.   However, the phased tonnage exemption period
mentioned above should provide some relief in  overcoming the
short-run rigidity particularly for smaller producers.
2.4.3  Unknown Directional Effects
     Several items that have unknown directional effects on
the cost estimates are listed in Table 2-9.  Of particular
relevance is the absence of variable production cost effects,
notably the difference in material costs.   The EPA was  unable
to obtain verifiable information on material cost  effects of
                             2-33

-------
reformulation.  Anecdotally, it was suggested that
solventborne material costs might rise in some situations
(e.g., those described in the comment) but might fall in
others (e.g., substitution of water carriers for solvent).
The net effect across all products is unknown.  Without any
hard data on the size or direction of material cost effects,
the EPA assumed no net material cost effects in the analysis.
     The compliance strategy decision is likely to be
complicated by issues other than cost that relate to the
profitability of reformulation.  If a product serves a narrow
market niche, reformulation may fundamentally alter the
product's attributes and erode the niche position.  In such a
case, the producer may find that choosing reformulation is not
profitable.  Although concerns regarding the regulation's
constraints on product differentiability are undoubtedly real
in some cases, this complexity is not explicitly addressed in
the quantitative analysis, primarily because of the difficulty
in observing both levels of and changes in product quality.
                              2-34

-------
                           SECTION 3
            ARCHITECTURAL COATINGS  MARKET ANALYSIS
     In this section, market effects of the regulatory action
are analyzed by presenting a model of how the outcome of the
reformulate/fee/withdrawal decision collectively affects
aggregate supply conditions and market outcomes in the
architectural coatings industry.  Then, operationalizing the
model using baseline market data and regulatory costs is
discussed to analyze the social cost effects of these market
outcomes in the architectural coatings industry.  The section
ends with an analysis of employment impacts.

3.1  MARKET EFFECTS OF FIRM RESPONSES TO REGULATION

     Firms' decisions to either reformulate or pay the
exceedance fee and remain in the market or to do neither and
exit the market collectively affect market outcomes  (price,
quantity, and welfare).  The change in market price depends on
the aggregate effects of the supply responses of the
individual producers.  Product exits will shift the aggregate
supply function inward, and marginal cost effects, such as the
per-unit fee, will shift the function upward.  This change can
be expected to raise the post-regulatory market price as the
new equilibrium is attained.  This process is described in
more detail in Appendix D.
                              3-1

-------
     Appendix D describes the methodology for incorporating
the reformulation/fee/withdrawal effects into a linked
multiple-market model framework.  This appendix also presents
the methodology for measuring the social welfare effects
(e.g., producer and consumer surplus) of the changes in market
equilibrium, which is affected by the regulation.
3.1.1  Model Execution and Results
     To estimate the effect of VOC content limits on
architectural coatings markets, a baseline characterization of
affected markets was constructed, empirically estimated shifts
in market supply and demand as a result of the regulations
were computed, and the market equilibrium model was applied to
the data to generate changes in prices and quantities in each
market.
     3.1.1.1  Baseline.  The coatings categories are grouped
into market segments, as defined in Table 2-3.  The price and
quantity data necessary to analyze market effects are not
provided in the survey conducted for this study but are
available from the U.S. Census Bureau Current Industrial
Reports publications.61  Because  the Census Bureau categorizes
architectural coatings products differently than they are
classified in the survey for this study, the market segments
were constructed so that data can be used from both sources
and provide the necessary level of resolution for market
analysis.  This process resulted in the 13 market segments
presented in Table 2-3.  Appendix A provides the details of
this product/market cross-referencing scheme.
     Table 2-3 lists quantities and value of shipments for
each market segment.  From these data, the average price for
each market was imputed.  Because the market segment price is
an average value, it may obscure heterogeneity of products
within each group.  Although the model aggregates different
products together to construct individual market segments, the
                              3-2

-------
objective in aggregating to the market segments  in Table 2-3
is to provide a level of resolution that both highlights
differences in the end use of the product  (e.g., exterior
coatings versus interior coatings) and distinguishes between
groups that will be affected differently by the  VOC content
regulation  (e.g., solventborne versus waterborne).  Eight of
the 13 segments consist of four pairs of related product
groups; one in each pair represents solventborne products and
the other represents waterborne products (e.g.,  interior
coatings).  Although the products in each of the paired market
segments possess different attributes, they perform similar
functions, thereby suggesting a high degree of product
substitutability in demand.  Demand elasticities were
estimated using procedures outlined in Appendix  A.  Supply
elasticities could not be econometrically estimated because of
data limitations; therefore, the aggregate supply elasticity
for each market segment was assumed to be unitary (1.0) .
     3.1.1.2  Quantifying Market Shocks.  The best-response
regulatory strategy for each stratum in the survey exceeding
the TOS limits is computed in the previous section.  For the
market analysis, the least-cost solution obtained previously
was compared to an estimate of per-unit profits.  If the cost
term exceeded the profit term, that stratum was  identified as
a "withdrawal" stratum.  Throughout this section, the market
results using upper bound of product reformulation cost
($14,573 per year) are presented unless otherwise indicated.
If the profit term exceeded the cost term and the least-cost
option was reformulation, the stratum was identified as a
"reformulation* stratum.  If the profit term exceeded the cost
term and the least-cost option was the fee, the  stratum was
identified as a "fee" stratum.  The model computes the total
quantity share of the withdrawal strata by summing the total
quantity from these strata (Qsx) and dividing by  the total
                              3-3

-------
baseline quantity from all strata for that  market segment in
the survey  (QST) .   This share was then multiplied by two-thirds
(the previously referenced share of all noncompliant formulas
needing reformulation)  to compute the market quantity subject
to the withdrawal option,  which is denoted  as the term RX.B

                      Rx =  (QSX/QST)  •  (2/3) .                  (3.1)

Similarly,  the model  computes the total quantity shares for
the reformulation R superscript) and the fee strata
(F superscript),  respectively:

                      RR = (QSR/QST) •  (2/3)                  (3.2)

                      RF =  (QSF/QST)  •  (2/3) .                  (3.3)

Finally, all  quantities not allocated to the exit,
reformulation, or fee actions can be viewed as the
unconstrained share:

                      R° =  1  - Rx - RR - RF.                  (3.4)

     To perform the market and welfare effects calculations,
the initial baseline  market-level values for the exiting,
reformulating, fee-paying,  and unconstrained sectors are
obtained for  reasons  explained in the methodology description
in Appendix D.  The model derives baseline  quantities by
multiplying the quantity shares derived from the survey data
by the initial baseline market quantity, Q0:
     •Multiplication by two-thirds incorporates the previously discussed
assumption that one-third of all products exceeding the limit can be
costlessly reformulated (and thus would not be withdrawn) .
                               3-4

-------
                         Qx =  Rx • Qo                       (3.5)

                         QR =  RR • Q0                       (3.6)

                         QF =  RF • Qo                       (3.7)

                         Qu =  Ru • Q0.                      (3.8)

     To quantify the supply effects of the per-unit  fee  on  the
fee-paying sector, as indicated in the equilibrium model
discussion in Appendix D, the model computes a value for the
unit fee as follows.
                   F = E F. • (QsiF/QsF)                   (3-9)

where FA is the fee for fee-paying stratum i,  QsiF is  stratum
i's quantity, and N is the number of fee strata  in the market.
     Finally, note that the measure of producer  surplus  losses
requires an estimate of marketwide reformulation costs.   The
model estimates this cost by taking the estimated number of
(surveyed and nonsurveyed) products in each market opting to
reformulate and multiplying this number by the annualized cost
of reformulation.
     Changes in Output and Price.  Table 3-1 reports the
estimated output and price effects of  the final  regulation.
In general, the annual output and price effects  are  quite
small relative to baseline values.  Price increases  are
typically well below 1 percent of baseline price, with the
exception of the solventborne primers  and undercoaters market
segment, where the projected price increase is $0.012/L
(0.4 percent).  In fact, to show any price effect, the change
in price is displayed to the fourth significant  digit.   In
                              3-5

-------
       TABLE 3-1.  REGULATORY EFFECTS ON ARCHITECTURAL COATINGS MARKET OUTPUT AND  PRICES
U)
No.
1
2
3
4
5
6_
7
8
9
10
11
12
13

Change in
Output
Produced
Market Segment (103 L)
Exterior & high performance—
solventborne
Exterior & high performance—
waterborne
Interior solventborne
Interior waterborne
Solventborne primers and
undercoaters
Waterborne primers and undercoaters
Solventborne clear coating, sealers,
stains
Waterborne clear coatings and stains
Architectural lacquers
Wood preservatives
Traffic marking paints
Special purpose
Industrial maintenance
Total
-195
69
-36
22
-349
52
-172
19
0
-2
-42
-15
-277
-926
% Change
from
Baseline
-0
0
-0
0
-0
0
-0
0
0
-0
-0
-0
-0
-0
.12%
.01%
.04%
.00%
.57%
.07%
.13%
.02%
.00%
.01%
.05%
.04%
.12%
.04%
Change in % Change
Price from
($1991) Baseline
$0
$0
$0
$0
$0
$0
$0
$0
$0
$0
$0
$0
$0

.0029
.0003
.0010
.0001
.0120
.0015
.0029
.0004
.0000
.0003
.0013
.0035
.0083

0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0

.09%
.02%
.03%
.01%
.43%
.07%
.10%
.02%
.00%
.02%
.09%
.08%
.24%

New
Quantity
(103 L)
162,
468,
94,
833,
60,
75,
134,
120,
40,
27,
91,
34,
230,
2,375,
741
414
900
456
950
264
506
757
Oil
446
025
554
984
006
New
Price
($/L)
$3.32
$2.24
$3.19
$2.10
$2.81
$2.14
$3.07
$2.21
$2.08
$1.45
$1.46
$4.10
$3.46


-------
other words, the average market price for nearly all 13 market
segments changes by less than 1 cent per unit.  Estimated
quantity reductions, across all architectural coatings markets
are approximately 926,000 L/yr.  This figure is less than
one-tenth of a percent of the industry baseline quantity.
     The results indicate differential impacts across market
segments.  For example, solventborne primers and Industrial
Maintenance show the largest reduction in output.  However,
four of the waterborne market segments show a net increase in
output produced.  These projected increases result as
consumers substitute away from the solventborne counterparts
because of the regulation-induced supply contraction and price
increases in those segments.  While noteworthy, these
increases are quite small in absolute terms.
     Total Social Costs.  The method for estimating changes in
consumer and producer welfare effects is demonstrated in
Appendix D.  In general, the net welfare effect  (social cost)
of the regulation equals the sum of consumer surplus, producer
surplus, and government surplus measures.  Costs are
distributed across parties in such a way that reformulating,
fee-paying, and exiting producers experience welfare losses by
incurring the regulatory costs  (or withdrawing products) and
consumers bear welfare costs through higher prices.  Changes
in consumer surplus measure losses to consumers from higher
prices and foregone consumption.  The total change in producer
surplus for each scenario equals the sum of the change in
producer surplus for the exiting products, fee-paying
products, reformulating products, and unconstrained products.
Losses to exiting products reflect the foregone profits the
producers would have received had the products stayed in the
market.  Losses for fee-paying products measure the net effect
of fee payments and recordkeeping costs plus the partial
                              3-7

-------
offset of these  losses  by  the rise in price caused by the
regulation.
     In Table  3-2,  the  producer losses for reformulating
producers total  -$20.4  million.  The model actually projects
total reformulation costs  of  $19.0 million, but $0.8 million
of total reformulation  costs  are recovered from offsetting
price gains accruing to the reformulating producers.
     Note that the  producer surplus effect for unconstrained
products is positive, reflecting the fact that producers of
these products gain the benefits of the regulation-induced
rise in price, without  any change in their cost structure
caused by the  regulation.  However, the welfare gains accruing
to the unconstrained products are transfers from coating
consumers and, as such,  should not be viewed as a net welfare
gain to society  due to  the regulation.
     The net annual welfare cost estimate is $22.3 million.
This is approximately $12  million  (41 percent) less than the
initial cost estimate for  the regulation under the
reformulation-only  scenario  (Table 2-2) .   Therefore,
accounting for economic responses substantially reduces the
estimate of regulatory  costs.  Welfare gains accrue to
unconstrained  producers through higher prices ($3.2 million)
and the recipient of exceedance fee revenues  ($4.0 million),
identified here  as  the  government sector.b  However,  the
government may redistribute these revenues back to any of the
parties affected directly  by  the regulations or back to the
citizenry via  the Federal  Treasury.  From society's perspec-
tive, the net  welfare effects of the current transfer method
(architectural producers to the government) or alternative
     'Note that  the difference in losses to fee-paying producers
 ($4.9 million) and government receipts  ($4.7 million) is due to two
 factors:  the payment of fee-related recordkeeping costs (+$0.6 million)
 and gains from offsetting price increases (-$0.4 million).
                               3-8

-------
                 TABLE 3-2.   ARCHITECTURAL COATINGS MARKET WELFARE  EFFECTS
Change in Producer Surplus ($1991)
No.
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13

Market Segment
Exterior & high
performance— solventborne
Exterior & high
performance-waterborne
Interior solventborne
Interior waterborne
Solventborne primers and
undercoaters
Waterborne primers and
undercoaters
Solventborne clear
coating, sealers, stains
Waterborne clear
coatings and stains
Architectural lacquers
Wood preservatives
Traffic marking paints
Special purpose
Industrial maintenance
Total
Exiting
Pro-
ducts
($103)
-31.73
-0.92
-13.89
-11.15
-138.79
0
-79.38
0
0
0
-33.16
-6.44
-268.98
-584.44
Fee- Paying
Products
($103)
-960.
-13.
-165.
-4.
-923.
-6.
-500.
-16.
0
-10.
0
-166.
-1,386.
-4,154.
37
60
22
35
23
96
31
76

67

63
52
61
Reformu-
lating
Producers'
($103)
-1,865
-276
-6,584
-64
-1,582
-17
-2,142
0
-416
-288
-1,475
-159
-5,571
-20,444
.42
.45
.09
.01
.38
.74
.77

.23
.86
.26
.66
.14
.01'
Uncon-
strained
(Net)
Total PS
Sector
($103)
252
148
48
107
454
116
230
43
0
4
47
107
1,600
3,163
.74
.42
.77
.77
.72
.42
.17
.36

.28
.91
.94
.84
.33
Total
($103)
-2,604
-142
-6,714
28
-2,189
91
-2,492
26
-416
-295
-1,460
-224
-5,625
-22,019
.79
.54
.43
.26
.67
.72
.30
.60
.23
.25
.51
.79
.80
.73
Change in
Consumer
Surplus
($1991
103)
-463
-161
-93
-107
-726
-116
-396
-43
0
-6
-120
-119
-1,907
-4,263
.76
.17
.62
.81
.69
.66
.04
.38

.89
.82
.53
.30
.66
Change in
Govern-
ment
Surplus
($1991
103)
910.87
1.82
128.44
1.74
913.45
4.51
481.06
1.85
0
9.47
0
140.84
1,370.29
3,964.32
Net
Welfare
Effects
($1991 103)
-2,157
-301
-6,679
-77
-2,002
-20
-2,407
-14
-416
-292
-1,581
-203
-6,162
-22,319
.68
.90
.62
.81
.91
.43
.28
.93
.23
.67
.33
.47
.80
.06
Actual reformulation cost is $19.0 million, but $0.8 million is recovered by producers through price increases.

-------
distributions (e.g., back to architectural producers) are
zero.
     As a point of comparison, market results were estimated
subject to the lower-bound cost assumption for reformulation
($6, 090/product/year) .   The total welfare cost under that
scenario is $13.2 million per year.  Because of the low
reformulation cost, few products would opt for the fee under
that cost scenario.

3 . 2  ARCHITECTURAL COATINGS INDUSTRY EMPLOYMENT IMPACTS

     Regulation-induced reductions in industry output may lead
to corresponding reductions in architectural coatings
employment.  Employment impacts are estimated by multiplying
the baseline industry employment level (L0)  by the
proportional change in industry output from its baseline
level:

                       AL = (AQ/Qo) • L0.                  (3.10)
This assumes a fixed relationship between output and
employment, at least for the marginal changes considered here.
     Table 3-3 presents the employment impacts results.  Total
employment for SIC 2581 is 51,100 employees.62-63  The
architectural coatings sector is a subset of SIC 2581, so the
architectural coatings employment was computed by taking the
ratio of architectural coatings output to SIC 2581 output and
multiplying it by SIC 2581 employment.  This produced an
estimate of approximately 26,100 employed in the architectural
coatings sector.
     The proportional change in architectural coatings output
was computed by taking the ratio of the change in output from
the market model  (summed across all market segments) over
                              3-10

-------
            TABLE 3-3.   ESTIMATED EMPLOYMENT  EFFECTS
                        Architectural  Coatings
                        Share of Baseline
     Output Change             Output*          Imputed Employment Change
        (103 L)                  (%)               (no. of employees)
         -926                 -0.039%           	     -10.2

  Baseline quantity and employment computations  are as follows:
Output
Sector
SIC 2581
Architectural
model
(103 gal)
1,229,800
627,723
(103 L)
4,654,793
2,375,933
Industry Employment
51,100 from Census
26,083 imputed from
output share
Sources:  U.S.  Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial Reports:  Paints
         and Allied Products, 1991.  Washington,  DC, Government Printing
         Office.  1992.
         U.S.  Department of Commerce.  1991 Annual Survey of Manufactures:
         Statistics for  Industry Groups and Industries.  Washington, DC,
         Government Printing Office.  1992.
baseline architectural coatings output.   This  computation was
performed for all  four scenarios of  the  market model.
      Given that  the output  change estimates in the market
model are relatively small,  it follows  that the  estimated
employment impacts are also small.   Under the  standard
scenario,  approximately 10  jobs are  lost nationwide,  a
0.04  percent reduction.
                                3-11

-------
                           SECTION 4
                  TRAFFIC COATING USER COSTS

     The economic analysis up to this point has focused
entirely on the primary impacts of the regulation, those borne
directly by producers in the architectural coatings industry
in the form of higher costs and indirectly by the consumers of
architectural products in the form of higher prices.  The
driving force of those impacts is the requirement that
noncompliant products must either be reformulated to a
compliant VOC level, be subject to a fee on the excess VOCs
over the allowable level, or be withdrawn from the market.
However, in this section a type of secondary impact is
considered, one that is caused by the costs that users of a
newly compliant product must incur to purchase the special
equipment necessary to apply the compliant coating.  The
analysis focuses exclusively on users of traffic marking
paints, primarily consisting of government entities such as
state transportation departments,  for whom the costs of
equipment switching are thought to be potentially significant.
While it is possible that other significant secondary impacts
exist, the extent and size of those is unknown and therefore
not quantified in this report.
     One complicating factor in estimating the cost of the
regulation for traffic coating users is the fact that
equipment replacement is a normal activity that would occur in
the absence of the regulation.  Therefore,  rather than viewing
the regulation as creating equipment replacement
                              4-1

-------
responsibilities, it is more correct to say that a different
(accelerated) time pattern of equipment replacement is
required.  This section presents the issue analytically and
then computes the incremental costs imposed on the population
of traffic coating users.
     According to the data collected for this study, the
service life of traffic marking coating trucks (stripers) is
typically 20 years.64  If the average truck is midway through
its replacement cycle, it will be replaced 10 years in the
future in the absence of the regulation.  However, to apply
waterborne coatings that are likely to result from the
regulation, users will be required to change the application
equipment.  The application equipment can be changed by either
purchasing new trucks with the proper equipment or
retrofitting the current trucks with special equipment to
handle the new coatings.  The incremental costs of each are
discussed in turn below.

4.1  TRUCK REPLACEMENT COST METHOD

     In an example of truck replacement, new trucks will be
purchased now rather than 10 years in the future,  and this
acceleration imposes costs on the government entity.  To
estimate the costs of this replacement acceleration process,
the cost of a large replacement truck ($250,000)  is used to
compute the net present value (NPV) today (at a 7  percent real
interest rate) of replacing the truck 10 years in  the future:

               NPV(-IO)  = $250,000/1.07" = $127,087.      (4.1)

Instead, the government entity is now required to  replace the
truck today at a cost of
                              4-2

-------
                         NPV(O)  =  $250.000.               (4.2)

Assuming no  salvage value  for  the  current  truck, the NPV cost
of accelerating the next replacement  is  then the difference  in
these values.

     Initial net effect =  NPV(O) - NPV(-IO)  = $122,913.   (4.3)

Thus, if the regulation just accelerates the next replacement,
the one-time cost of that  acceleration is  approximately
$123,000.
     However, accelerating the replacement of the current
equipment by 10 years also accelerates the next round of
equipment replacements  (from 30 years hence  to 20 years hence)
and so on.  Thus, the effects reverberate  into all future
replacement decisions.  This point is demonstrated graphically
by the alternative time lines of expenditures in Figure 4-1.
The regulation effectively moves up the  entire replacement
schedule by 10 years.  The computation must  therefore be
expanded to measure the present value of the current and all
future adjustments.  To start, the present value of an initial
$250,000 cash expenditure  repeated every 20  years thereafter
is computed:

          V(0)  = $250,000  + $250,000*(1/( (1.07)20 - 1))
               = $337,118.                                 (4.4)

Without the regulation,  this stream of costs would be deferred
10 years into the future.   Evaluating this in present value
terms gives

               V(-10)= V(0)/1.07"  = $171,373.             (4.5)
                              4-3

-------
                               $250,000
                                           $250,000
                 $250.000
  Cost Schedule Without
      Accelerated
      Replacement
                     YMT
                                 10     20     30     40
                    50
                         $250.000
$250,000
$250.000
   Cost  Schedule With
      Accelerated
      Replacement
                     T*ar
                                 10
                                       20
        30
                                                   40
        50 .  .
   Figure 4-1.  Cost schedules with and without accelerated
                          replacement.
Thus,  the  difference in present  value between  the  two
replacement cost streams is  the  total cost of  accelerating
this and all future purchases:
           Total net effect = V(0)  - V(-10) = $165,744.
                        (4.6)
     This  can be viewed as a  one-time cost of the regulation
for the  component of a government entity's traffic coating
striper  fleet that is 10 years  old.   This explicitly  accounts
for the  present value of the  regulation's effect on all  future
replacement costs.
                               4-4

-------
4.2  EQUIPMENT RETROFIT METHOD

     An alternative  to early replacement  of a  traffic coating
truck  is to retrofit the current  truck with equipment that can
use the compliant coating.  This  allows the government entity
to continue to use the current  truck until the end of its
service life, at which time it  will be replaced with a new
truck  that is able to apply compliant coatings.  Assuming that
the replacement schedule for the  truck is unaffected by the
retrofit, then none  of the costs  of accelerated replacement
just discussed will  apply.  This  is demonstrated in
Figure 4-2.  As with the example  in Figure 4-1, replacement
costs without the regulation would occur  10, 30, 50, etc.
years hence.  Under  the retrofit  example, the  government
entity incurs the retrofit costs  now (Year 0)  but still
maintains the same future replacement cost schedule.
Therefore, assuming  no salvage  value for  the retrofit
equipment, the one-time cost of the regulation is simply the
cost of purchasing the retrofit equipment in Year 0.  The
present value of all  future costs is identical with and
without the regulation.

4.3  NATIONAL INCREMENTAL COST CALCULATION

     The cost of the regulation for traffic coating users is
computed separately  for the estimated current fleet of  medium
stripers (Table 4-1)  and large stripers (Table 4-2).  Costs
are aggregated across both types and summarized in Table  4-3.
                              4-5

-------
     Replacement Cost
     Schedule Without
         Retrofit
                                $250.000
                                           $250,000
                             $250.000
                      Y«ar
                                  10     20
                                             30
                                                   40     50 .
      Replacement Cost
       Schedule With
         Retrofit
T
                                $250,000
                  $250,000
$250.000
                      T**r
                                  10    20
                                             30
                                                   40     50
    Figure 4-2.   Replacement cost  schedules with and without
                        equipment retrofit.
     Data on the vintage of the national  fleets of medium and
large  stripers are provided in the  traffic coating analysis
report by ERG.65  The government entities  facing the decision
to replace trucks now or to retrofit  each vintage striper in
the  fleet are assumed to select the option that minimizes the
present value of costs.  When the PV  of a new truck vs.
retrofit is calculated, it appears  that it would cost less for
government entities to retrofit medium trucks that are under
15 years old than to purchase new trucks.   As a result, all
medium stripers currently older than  15 years (i.e.,  will be
replaced within 5 years) are projected to be scrapped  (at no
                               4-6

-------
    TABLE 4-1.   NATIONAL INCREMENTAL  COST OF  TRAFFIC  COATING
  EQUIPMENT REPLACEMENT AND RETROFITS-MEDIUM STRIPERS  ($1996)
Assumptions
         Baseline year equipment vintage
         Replacement cost
         T =  service life
         PV of replacement cost every 20
         years
         Retrofit cost
         Retrofit cutoff age
         i =  discount rate
         Salvage value

.Replacement scheme
    1999
$100,000
      20
$134,847 computed

 $35,000
      15
    0.07
       0
            This  is the present value (PV)  (Year 0) of accelerating the
            replacement schedule.
                   PV
               Replacement     PV                 Number
      Scheduled    Cost    Replacement      PV        of     PV Total
      Replace-   Without    Cost  With  Incremental Replace-  Replace-  Annualized
 Age  ment Year Regulation Regulation     Cost      ments      ment       Cost
20
19
18
17
16
0
1
2
3
4
134,847
126,025
117,781
110,075
102,874
134,847
134,847
134,847
134,847
134,847
0
8,822
17,066
24,772
31,973
150
150
150
150
150
0
1,323,265
2,559,962
3,715,753
4,795,932
0
92,629
179,197
260,103
335,715
                                                         12,394,912   867,644
                                                                   (continued)
                                     4-7

-------
    TABLE  4-1.   NATIONAL INCREMENTAL COST  OF TRAFFIC COATING
  EQUIPMENT  REPLACEMENT  AND  RETROFITS-MEDIUM STRIPERS  ($1996)
                                 (CONTINUED)


Retrofit scheme
         Assume that replacement schedule is unaffected by retrofit.
         Therefore service life of retrofit  is equal to the remaining  life of  the
         current equipment.
Scheduled

Replacement =
Useful Life of PV per
Retrofit Retrofit Retrofit
15 5
14 6
13 7
12 8
11 9
10 10
9 11
8 12
7 13
6 14
5 15
4 16
3 17
2 16
1 19


35,000
35,000
35,000
35,000
35,000
35,000
35,000
35,000
35,000
35,000
35,000
35,000
35,000
35,000
35,000



Number of
Retrofits
150
90
90
90
90
90
90
90
90
0
0
0
0
0
0

Sum

PV of
Retrofits
5,250,000
3,150,000
3,150,000
3,150,000
3,150,000
3,150,000
3,150.000
3,150,000
3,150,000
0
0
0
0
0
0
30,450,000
42,844,912

Annual i zed
Cost
367,500
220,500
220,500
220,500
220,500
220,500
220,500
220,500
220,500
0
0
0
0
0
0
2,131,500
2,999,144
* The PV of the replacement scheme  is the PV cost of an accelerated  replacement
  schedule.  This  is a one-time event; thus, we annualize this value by multiplying
  it by the discount rate.  All service life issues are implicitly captured in the
  PV calculation.

b The PV of each retrofit is $35,000.  This is also a one-time cost  (i.e., it does
  not need to be repeated).   Therefore, it is also annualized by multiplying by the
  discount rate.

Note:  The replacement of retrofitted vehicles will follow the same  schedule as
      without regulation, so there is no replacement acceleration taking place.
                                     4-8

-------
    TABLE 4-2.   NATIONAL  INCREMENTAL  COST OF  TRAFFIC COATING
   EQUIPMENT REPLACEMENT  AND  RETROFITS-LARGE  STRIPERS  ($1996)

Assumptions
         Baseline year equipment vintage             1999
         Replacement cost                       $250,000
         T = service life                             20
         PV of replacement cost every 20         $337,118 computed
         years
         Retrofit cost                          $45,000
         Retrofit cutoff age                          17
         i = discount rate                          0.07
         Salvage value                                0

Replacement scheme
      **** This is the  PV (Year  0) of accelerating the replacement schedule.

                    PV
               Replacement      PV                  Number
      Scheduled     Cost    Replacement     PV        of     PV Total
      Replace-   Without    Cost With Incremental Replace-  Replace-  Annualized
 Age  ment Year  Regulation  Regulation     Cost      ments    ment       Cost
20
19
18

0
1
2

337,
315,
294,

118
063
452

337,
337,
337,

118
118
118

0
22,054
42,666

25
25
25


551,
1,066,
1,618,
0
361
651
Oil

38,
74,
113,
0
595
666
261
(continued)
                                     4-9

-------
    TABLE 4-2.   NATIONAL INCREMENTAL COST OF TRAFFIC COATING
        EQUIPMENT REPLACEMENT AND RETROFITS-LARGE STRIPERS
                            ($1996)(CONTINUED)


Retrofit scheme
         Assume that the replacement schedule  is unaffected by retrofit.
Scheduled
Replacement =
Useful Life of PV per
Retrofit Retrofit Retrofit
17 3
16 4
15 5
14 6
13 7
12 8
11 9
10 10
9 11
8 12
7 13
6 14
5 15
4 16
3 17
2 18
1 19


45,000
45,000
45,000
45,000
45,000
45,000
45,000
45,000
45,000
45,000
45,000
45,000
45,000
45,000
45,000
45,000
45,000


Number of
Retrofits
25
25
25
15
15
15
15
15
15
15
15
0
0
0
0
0
0

Sum
PV of
Retrofits
1,125,000
1,125,000
1,125,000
675,000
675,000
675,000
675,000
675,000
675,000
675,000
675,000
0
0
0
0
0
0
8,775,000
10,393,011
Annual! zed
Cost
78,750
78,750
78,750
47,250
47,250
47,250
47,250
47,250
47,250
47,250
47,250
0
0
0
0
0
0
614,250
727,511
*  The PV of the replacement scheme  is the PV cost  of an accelerated replacement
  schedule.  This  is a one-time  event; thus, we annualize this  value by multiplying
  it by the discount rate.   All  service life issues are implicitly captured in the
  PV calculation.

b  The PV of each retrofit is $45,000.  This is also a one-time  cost (i.e.,  it does
  not need to be repeated).  Therefore, it is also annual!zed by multiplying by  the
  discount rate.

Note:  The replacement of retrofitted vehicles will follow the  same schedule as
      without regulation,  so there is no replacement acceleration taking place.
                                     4-10

-------
   TABLE 4-3.   NATIONAL INCREMENTAL COST SUMMARY FOR TRAFFIC
                   COATING EQUIPMENT ($1996)

 Striper Type                PV of Cost      Annualized Cost
 Medium (see Table 4-1)      $42,844,912         $2,999,144
 Large (see Table 4-2)	$10,393,011	$727,511
 Total                       $53,237,923         $3,726,655

salvage value) and replaced with new trucks, while all medium
stripers under 15 years old are projected to retrofit the
current vehicles.  The corresponding age threshold for this
decision is 17 years for large stripers.
     Present value costs are computed for each vintage year,
dependent on the replacement/retrofit decision, and then are
multiplied by the number of stripers of that vintage in the
fleet.  This calculation is then summed across all vintage
years to estimate the present value of national costs.  As
Table 4-3 indicates, the present value of total national costs
is estimated at $53.2 million - $42.8 million for medium
stripers and $10.4 million for large stripers.
     This present value figure is the one-time cost of the
regulation for the government entities faced with equipment
replacement. For comparability with the other estimates in
this analysis, this figure must be expressed in annualized
terms.  Because the acceleration  (and its costs) are a one-
time event not to be repeated in the future, the appropriate
form of annualization  is to compute the corresponding
perpetual annuity value-the amount, if paid out in annual
installments into perpetuity, that would have a present value
equal to the one-time  cost estimate. This number is computed
simply by multiplying  the one-time cost estimate by the
discount rate of 7 percent
                             4-11

-------
     Annualized cost = ($53.2 million) • .07 = $3.7 million

This is the conceptually correct figure for the annualized
costs incurred by government entities to switch equipment for
traffic marking coating application.  This annual estimate is
used to compute cost-effectiveness measures in the next
section.
                              4-12

-------
                           SECTION 5
               SOCIAL COST-EFFECTIVENESS ANALYSIS
     The social  cost  estimates  from the market analysis  and
the estimate of  traffic  coating user costs can be used to
compute measures of the  social  cost-effectiveness of  the
regulation.  The distinction of "social* cost-effectiveness  is
made to illuminate the fact that the costs evaluated  are the
net costs imposed on  society, i.e., the net welfare costs
estimated in the architectural  coatings market plus the
resource costs incurred  by traffic coating users to switch
application equipment.
     The measure of social cost-effectiveness is computed as
follows:
                  SCE =  (|AWF|  + TMEC)/|AE|.              (5.1)

|AWF| is the absolute value of  the aggregate annual net  change
in welfare  (i.e., total  social  costs), summed across  all
markets in the market analysis.  TMEC is the annualized
traffic marking  equipment costs, and |AE| is the absolute
value of emission reductions.   The |AWF| of 20.2 million is
produced by the  market model.   The TMEC value is estimated at
$3.7 million in  the previous section and is adjusted  to
$3.3 million {1991 dollars) for comparison with the market
results, leading to a total social cost estimate of
$23.5 million.    For external reporting purposes,  all numbers
will be converted to  1996 dollars later in this section.

                              5-1

-------
     The emissions  reduction estimate needs some elaboration.
To correspond with  the cost estimates, a national estimate of
emissions reduction must be used.  The baseline estimate of
national VOC emissions from regulated architectural coatings
products is 509,900 Mg.*'66  Given the  reduction  of  20.6 percent
in 1998, the aggregate emissions reduction in 1998 is
105,075 Mg, which is AET.   However,  the emissions target must
be adjusted by two  market-related factors:  foregone emissions
reduction due to selecting the fee option and changes  (net
reduction) in emissions due to regulation- induced changes in
industry output.
     The first adjustment,  AE™, was computed by  taking the
total quantity of "exceedance" emissions for products  electing
the fee option.  These targeted emissions reductions will not
be accomplished because of the fee option:

                     AEra =  (AE/VAEs1)  • AET.                 (5.2)
     The second  adjustment was computed by taking the  ratio of
the change in  industry output to baseline industry output and
multiplying by baseline industry emissions:

                       AE° = (AQ/Q0)  • E0.                   (5.3)

AQ is  the change in industry output, which is the sum  of
market-level changes,  Q0  is baseline industry output
 (2.375 billion liters),  and E0 is  baseline emissions
 (509,000 Mg indicated above).
     Thus, the net emissions reduction is computed as  follows:
      This estimate is based on a national baseline emissions estimate
provided by Eastern Research Group of 560,900  tons, which is converted to
Mg by multiplying by the  ratio  of tons/Mg = 0.9072.  The result is a
national estimate of 509,900 Mg.
                               5-2

-------
                     AE = AET + AEFR + AEQ.                 (5.4)

Absolute reductions are reported in Table 5-1.  The net
reduction equals the targeted reduction, less foregone
emissions reductions (due to fee), plus emission changes due
to changes in industry output via regulation-induced market
interactions.
     The analysis focuses on computing social cost per Mg of
emissions reduction based on the market welfare costs and
traffic marking coating user costs estimated in the previous
sections.  Table 5-1 presents the results.  The social cost-
effectiveness estimate is $247/Mg.
     This estimate allows for an evaluation of cost-
effectiveness implications of the fee option.  Allowing the
fee reduces social costs  (compared to the static national
reformulation cost estimate of $34 million) by about
$12 million but foregoes about 1,802 Mg of emissions
reduction, about 1.7 percent of the targeted reductions.
Dividing the cost savings by foregone reductions approximates
the marginal social cost of the foregone reductions.  This
figure is $6,580/Mg, which is substantially higher than the
$247/Mg average social cost-effectiveness measure reported in
Table 5-1.  This indicates that the fee's main effect is to
reduce the most expensive emission reductions.
     An important implication of these estimates is that the
fee option, while leading to a substantial reduction in the
social costs of the regulation, does not significantly
undercut the emissions reduction target.  Moreover, by
charging the VOC exceedance fee, firms that opt for the fee
have a continued incentive to achieve marginal reductions in
VOC content.
                              5-3

-------
                          TABLE 5-1.    SOCIAL COST-EFFECTIVENESS  ESTIMATES
Social Cost:
Architectural
Coatings
Market
($1991)
22,319,063

Traffic
Coating
User Costs
($1991)
3,269,994


Total
Social Cost
($1991)
25,589,057

National
Emissions
Reduction*
(Mg)
105,075
Estimated
Foregone
Emissions
Change1"
(Mg)
1,802
Estimated
Market
Output
Adjustment0
(Mg)
198

Net
Emission
Reduction*
(Mg)
103.471

Social
Cost per
Mg
($1991)
$247
• National estimate of baseline emissions  (509,900 Mg)  times  0.2061  (estimated proportional emissions reduction  in
  1998).

b National emissions  foregone due to adoption of exceedance fee, as estimated in architectural coatings market model.

c Baseline emissions  times ratio of industry market quantity  reduction to baseline industry output.

a Net emissions  reduction = targeted reduction - foregone reduction + quantity adjustment.

-------
5.1  CONVERSION OF IMPACTS TO CURRENT DOLLARS

     As indicated previously, all impacts presented in the
analysis are in constant 1991 dollars.  Some commenters
indicated a preference for values to be expressed in more
recent years.  Therefore, this section provides a
demonstration of how 1991 dollars can be converted into a
value closer to the current year.  This conversion is
performed using the 3GDP price deflator.  At the time of this
analysis,  the most recent year of data was for 1996; thus a
conversion is provided for 1996.  Given that the GDP index in
1991 is 97.4 and in 1996 the index is 111.0, a conversion
factor of 1.1397 can be applied to any value in the report.
Table 5-2 demonstrates the conversion to 1996 dollars.  The
estimated annual net social welfare cost of the regulation of
$25.6 million in 1991 dollars converts to $29.2 million in
1996 dollars.  Thus, social cost-effectiveness estimate
converts from $247 Mg ($1991) to $282 Mg ($1996).
   TABLE 5-2.   CONVERSION OF SUMMARY IMPACTS TO 1996 DOLLARS
   Impact Estimate
        $1991
      $1996
 Net social cost
 Net social cost per
 Mg of emissions
 reduction
$25.6 million
$247/Mg
$29.2 million
$282/Mg
                              5-5

-------

-------
                           SECTION 6
                SMALL BUSINESS IMPACT ANALYSIS

     The Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA) of 1980
(5 U.S.C. 601, et seq.),  as amended by the Small Business
Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act of 1996  (SBREFA),  requires
the EPA to give special consideration to the effect of federal
regulations on small entities and to consider regulatory
options that might mitigate any such impacts.  The EPA is
required to prepare a regulatory flexibility analysis,
including consideration of regulatory options for reducing any
significant impact, unless the Agency determines that a rule
will not have a significant economic impact on a substantial
number of small entities.
     The Agency prepared analyses to support both the proposed
and final rules to meet the requirements of the RFA as
modified by SBREFA.  The Agency undertook these analyses
because of the large presence of small entities in the
architectural coatings industry and because the initial impact
analysis indicated that there could be a significant economic
impact on a substantial number of small entities if mitigating
regulatory options were not adopted for the rule.  The
analysis supporting the proposed rule was published in the
report titled, "Economic Impact and Regulatory Flexibility
Analysis of Air Pollution Regulations: Architectural and
Industrial Maintenance Coatings* (June 1996).  The proposed
rule contained a number of provisions to mitigate the rule's
                              6-1

-------
impact on small businesses, and the Agency requested comment
on additional measures to reduce the impacts.
     This section presents the small business impacts and the
final regulatory flexibility analysis,  including responses to
significant issues raised by public comments on proposed
compliance options to mitigate the rule's impact on small
entities.  After evaluating public comment on the proposed
mitigating options, EPA made a number of changes to the
proposed rule to further mitigate the rule's small business
impacts.  As a result, the Agency believes that it is highly
unlikely that the rule will have a significant economic impact
on a substantial number of small entities.  However, in light
of the Agency's inability to quantify the effect of the
mitigating options, the EPA has elected to conduct a
regulatory flexibility analysis and to prepare a SBREFA
compliance guide to eliminate any potential dispute on whether
EPA has fulfilled SBREFA requirements.

6.1  BACKGROUND AND AFFECTED ENTITIES

     Small businesses can be defined using the criteria
prescribed in the RFA or some other criteria identified by
EPA.  The SBA's general size standard definitions for Standard
Industrial Classification  (SIC) codes is one way to define
small businesses.  These size standards are presented either
by number of employees or by annual receipt levels, depending
on the SIC code.  For SIC 2851, Paint and Allied Products (of
which architectural manufacturers represent approximately
40 percent), the SBA defines small business as fewer than 500
employees.  The coatings manufacturing industry, however, is
not labor-intensive.  For example, given the average value of
shipments per employee (based on data presented in Sections 1
and 3), a firm with 400 employees might have close to
                              6-2

-------
$100 million in sales (1991 $) .  Therefore, use of this SBA
definition would result in almost all firms in the
architectural coatings industry being classified as small,
which does not appear appropriate given the sales level of
many firms.  Alternatively, based on input from the regulatory
negotiation process, the EPA has defined small businesses as
having less than $10 million in annual architectural coatings
sales and less than $50 million in total annual sales of all
products.  Using this definition, the section assesses the
baseline presence of small producers in specific architectural
coatings markets.  The distribution of small producers by
market segment is important because impacts vary substantially
by market segment.  After the baseline assessment, an analysis
is performed to estimate the extent to which specialization in
higher VOC products causes small companies to incur
disproportionate impacts.  This is followed by an estimate of
the average impacts of regulatory compliance on small
architectural coatings companies, as measured by the ratio of
compliance costs to sales.  The role of special provisions
such as the fee and small tonnage exemption allowance are also
examined in terms of their mitigating impacts on small
producers.
6.1.1  Potentially Affected Entities
     A regulatory action to reduce VOC emissions from
architectural coatings products will potentially affect the
business entities that produce the products.  Firms, or
companies, that produce architectural coatings are legal
business entities that have the capacity to conduct business
transactions and make business decisions.  Figure 6-1 shows
the chain of ownership may be as simple as one facility owned
by one company  (firm) or as complex as multiple facilities
owned by subsidiary companies.
                              6-3

-------
       Parent Company
Parent Company
Parent Company
 (Direct Owner)
      Other Companies
       or Legal Entities
         Subsidiary
         Company
        (Direct Owner)
           I
  Subsidiary
  Company
(Direct Owner)
          Facility
    I
   Facility
   Facility
                                B
                Figure  6-1.   Chain of ownership.

     Determining the total  number of firms  that will be
affected by the regulation  is difficult because most of  the
available  Census data are reported at the four-digit SIC code,
and architectural coatings  manufacturers, for whom this
regulation applies, are a subset of the entire coatings
industry represented by SIC 2851.  The 1987 Census of
Manufactures,  Industry Series:  Paint and Allied Products
identified 530 companies with shipments of  $100,000 or more
                                6-4

-------
that  manufacture architectural and special  purpose coatings.a>67
For the purpose of this  analysis, 500 architectural coating
manufacturers were assumed to exist.  Data  from the
Architectural and Industrial Surface Coatings  VOC Emissions
Inventory Survey (the survey) conducted by  the National Paint
and Coatings Association provided data for  116 firms, 36 of
which identified themselves as having under $10 million in
annual net sales.b-68   While small businesses represent about
31 percent of the firms  in the survey, a  larger share of
nonsurveyed firms appear to fall in the small  business
category.0
6.1.2  Regulatory Requirements
      As discussed in Section 2,  the regulation constrains
firms that produce architectural coatings products over the
VOC content limits in one of three ways:

      •  requires  they produce products with VOC content under
        the established set of limits,
      •  imposes a fee on each unit of product that exceeds  the
        limits established in the regulation, or
      •  requires  they withdraw the product from the market.

Thus,  absent the small tonnage exemption,  firms with a heavy
(baseline)  concentration of products above  the limit for their
respective product categories are more tightly constrained by
     •These are the two Census categories within SIC 2851 where most of
the architectural coatings products are represented, and this figure
includes companies that produce architectural products, whether or not it
is their primary product.
     Twelve survey respondents did not indicate company size.
     •The 116 survey respondents comprise about one-fifth of the firms
making architectural coatings products but account for about three-fourths
of industry output.  Thus the nonsurveyed firms are relatively numerous but
produce relatively little volume. '

                               6-5

-------
the regulation than those with a  lighter  concentration of
above-limit products, all else equal.

6 .2  ANALYSIS

     The quantitative analysis of small business  impacts  draws
from the NPCA survey data for the 36 companies  classified as
small  (less than $10 million in architectural sales  and
$50 million in total sales).  While this  is  a relatively  small
sample of all potentially impacted small  companies  (less  than
10 percent), it is assumed  that the surveyed small companies
are fairly representative of the  nonsurveyed small companies.
As described below, efforts were  made  to  expand the  sample
beyond the 36 surveyed small companies, but  the inability to
estimate firm-specific costs made such an extension
problematic.  Therefore the results of this  analysis should be
interpreted with the usual  caution surrounding  small samples.
6.2.1  Baseline Market Presence of Small  Architectural
       Coatings Producers
     Small business presence in specific  coatings markets
indicates one dimension of how small firms may  be affected by
the regulation.  For certain product markets, small  businesses
predominate and thus may be disproportionately  affected if
limits are particularly restrictive on those categories.
Table 6-1 lists the coatings product categories provided  in
the survey.69  The  survey data represent producers that account
for approximately  three-quarters  of the total industry product
volume.d
     Small companies produce more than 20 percent of the
products in the survey, but these products account for just
3.6 percent of total coatings volume and  3.7 percent of total
     "This is based on the ratio of Census product volume  (part of the
total SIC 2851 volume)  to the survey product volume.
                              6-6

-------
TABLE 6-1.
SMALL BUSINESS PRESENCE IN THE ARCHITECTURAL COATINGS MARKET":
                 SURVEY POPULATION
Total Survey Population
(116 respondents)11
Market
Segment Regulation
12
13
3,4
3.4
1,2
1,2
5,6
13
1,2
1,2
7,8
7,8
11
7,8
7,8
Bond breakers
Magnesite
cement
coatings
Flat, interior
Nonflat,
interior
Flat, exterior
Nonflat,
exterior
Primers
Industrial
maintenance
coatings
Roof coatings
Bituminous
coatings and
mastics
Stains,
semitransp.
Stains, opaque
Traffic
marking paints
Waterproofing
sealers, clear
Average
Imputed Volume
Revenues' Number per
Sales (10' of Product
(10' L) $1991) Products (103 L)
NR
NR
440,498
316,786
188,764
152,705
109,850
92,412
89,515
79,051
53,057
47,168
46,886
37,393
26.184
NA
NA
973,502
700,097
473,799
383,290
268,034
318,820
224,683
198,418
141,131
125,466
67,985
99,464
69,649
1
2
391
529
344
494
634
652
80
34
205
125
85
71
215
NA
NA
1,126.6
598.8
548.7
309.1
173.3
141.7
1,118.9
2,325.0
258.8
377.3
551.6
526.7
121.8
Small Business (36 respondents)
Share of
Total Imputed Number
Sales Sales Volume Revenues of
(10J L) (%) (105 $1991) Products
NR
0.0
4,214
2,802
3,320
4,765
2,780
2,603
19,939
4,450
602
39
5,649
318
3,177
100.0
NA
1.0
0.9
1.8
3.1
2.5
2.8
22.3
5.6
1.1
0.1
12.0
0.9
12.1
NA
0
9,313
6,192
8,334
11,960
6,782
8,980
50,046
11,170
1,601
103
8,192
846
8,452
1
0.0
81
87
92
155
137
78
20
22
18
11
21
14
48
Share of
Total
Products
100.0
0.0
20.7
16.4
26.7
31.4
21.6
12.0
25.0
64.7
8.8
8.8
24.7
19.7
22.3
Average Volume
per Product
(101 L)
NA
0.0
52.0
32.2
36.1
30.7
20.3
33.4
996.9
202.3
33.4
3.5
269.0
22.7
66.2

-------
TABLE 6-1.  SMALL BUSINESS PRESENCE IN THE ARCHITECTURAL COATINGS MARKET":
                       SURVEY POPULATION (CONTINUED)
Total Survey Population
(116 respondents)"
Market
Segment Regulation
Number Category
12


1.2

9
7.8
0\ 10

00
12

5,6


7,8

10


5,6
13

3

7


10

Metallic
pigmented
coatings
High-
performance
Lacquers
Sealers
Clear wood
preservatives

Dry fog
coatings
Quick dry
primers.
undercoaters
waterproofing
sealers , opaque
Semitransp.
wood
preservatives
Undercoaters
Mastic texture
coatings
Quick dry
enamels
Shellacs, clear
& opaque
solventborne
Opaque wood
preservatives
Sales
(105 L)
22,163


19,233

17,351
15,375
15,064


14,107

13,612


10,214

8,902


7,096
6,443

6,390

3,937


2,974

Imputed
Revenues'
<10l $1991)
90,868


48,274

36,090
40,898
21,843


57,837

33,212


27,169

12,909


17,313
22,230

20,321

12,047


4,312

Number
of
Average
Volume
per
Product
Products (10' L)
128


186

65
100
15


68

40


29

32


43
42

85

11


8

173.1


103.4

266.9
153.8
1,004.3


207.4

340.3


352.2

278.2


165.0
153.4

75.2

357.9


371.7

Sales
(101 L)
2,390


145

4,384
350
0


63

0.0


17

0.0


66
2,637

280

0.0


0.0

Small Business (36 respondents)
Share of
Total Sales imputed
Volume Revenues
(%(
10.8


0,8

25.3
2.3
0.0


0.4

0.0


0.2

0.0


0.9
40.9

4.4

0.0


0.0

(101 $1991)
9,798


364

9,118
932
0


259

0


44

0.0


162
9,096

890

0.0


0.0

Number
of
Share of Average
Total volume
Products per Product
Products (%)
50


23

13
9
0


7

0.0


2

0.0


7
10

14

0.0


0.0

39.1


12.4

20.0
9.0
0.0


10.3

0.0


6.9

0.0


16.3
23.8

16.5

0.0


0.0

(101 L)
47.8


6.3

337.2
38.9
0.0


9.0

0.0


8.4

0.0


9.5
263.7

20.0

0.0


0.0


-------
  TABLE 6-1.  SMALL BUSINESS PRESENCE  IN THE ARCHITECTURAL COATINGS MARKET":   SURVEY
                                  POPULATION  (CONTINUED)
Total Survey Population
(116 respondents )b
Market
Segment
Number
13
12
12
12
12
12
12
10
13
13
12

Regulation
Category
Sanding
sealers
Multicolor
coatings
Concrete
curing
compounds
Form release
compounds
Graphic arts
coatings
Pretreatment
wash primers
Swimming pool
coatings
Below ground
wood
preservatives
High
temperature
coatings
Appurtenances
Antigraffiti
coatings
Sums /averages
Sales
(10' L)
2,796
1,613
1,256
1,026
994
668
656
507
483
205
42
1,853,623"
Imputed
Revenues0
(10' $1991)
9,648
6,614
5,148
4,206
4,075
2,739
2,689
736
1,665
707
172
4,528,916
Number
of
Products
41
4
6
5
30
18
27
8
44
7
8
4,920
Average
Volume
per
Product
(10J L)
68.2
403.3
209.3
205.2
33.1
37.1
24.3
63.4
11.0
29.3
5.3
376.8
Sales
(10> L)
80
0
NR
0
251.3
11.3
126.4
0
4.4
200.5
40.1
65,914
Small Business (36 respondents)
Share of
Total sales
Volume
(%)
2.9
0
NA
0
25.3
1.7
19.3
0
0.9
97.9
95.3
3.6
Imputed
Revenues
(101 $1991)
277
0
NA
0
1,030.5
46.2
518.1
0
15.1
691.6
164.2
166,022
Number
of
Products
8
0
1.0
0
20.0
4.0
14.0
0
9.0
5.0
6.0
992
Share of
Total
Products
(%)
19.5
0
16.7
0
66.7
22.2
51.9
0
20.5
71.4
75.0
20.2
Average
Volume
per
Product
(10' L)
10.0
0
NA
0
12.6
2.8
9.0
0
0.5
40.1
6.7
66.4
See notes at end of table.
(continued)

-------
            TABLE  6-1.   SMALL  BUSINESS PRESENCE  IN THE ARCHITECTURAL COATINGS MARKET":
                                       SURVEY POPULATION  (CONTINUED)



    •  Small businesses are defined as producing less than $10 million in architectural coatings products or
      less than $50 million in total sales.

    b  The survey had 116 respondents and 36 of those identified themselves as having under  $10 million in
      annual sales.   Twelve survey respondents did not report company size.

    c  Revenues were imputed using  average prices taken from Section 2.   A weighted average  was used when the
      product category belongs in  two market segments.

    d  The actual total volume reported in the survey is 1,853,658,716 L.   The difference here, 35,677 L, is
      attributed to bond breakers  and magnesite cement coatings,  and waterborne quick dry enamels, which are
      not reported.   The quantity  reported here is slightly greater than the total survey quantity used in the
      market analysis because quantities in the survey that were identified as either "exempt* or "unknown*
      (with respect to solventborne or waterborne) were not included in the total  for the market analysis.

i    NR =  Not reported due to disclosure of individual companies.
»->
0   NA =  Not available.

    Source:  Industry Insights.  Architectural and Industrial Maintenance Surface Coatings VOC Emissions
            Inventory Survey.   Prepared for National Paint and Coatings Association in cooperation with the
            AIM Regulatory Negotiation Industry Caucus.   Final Draft Report.   1993.

-------
revenue.  This is evidence that small businesses tend to
produce lower volumes per product.  The average price per
product in the small business segment is $2.52/L, compared to
$2.44/L for the industry.  The largest volume category for
small producers is roof coatings, at 19.9 million L/yr.  Small
producers comprise just over 22 percent of the volume in that
category.  Small businesses produce over 95 percent of the
total volume of antigraffiti coatings, but the volume is quite
low, with six products totaling about 40,060 L.
     Other categories in which small producers comprise more
than 20 percent of the market volume are lacquers, mastic
texture coatings,  graphic arts coatings, bond breakers, and
appurtenances.  In addition to roof coatings, small producers
collectively produce over 4 million L in the following
categories:  traffic marking paints, exterior nonflats,
bituminous coatings, lacquers, and interior flats.
6.2.2  VOC Content of Small Business Products:  Technology and
       Specialization Effects
     The extent to which small businesses are affected by the
architectural coatings regulation will depend partly on the
average VOC content of small business products relative to the
industry average.   Table 6-2 presents the average baseline VOC
content for products manufactured by small businesses as
compared with those manufactured by the industry as a whole.70
Small business products generate approximately 6.2 percent of
total VOC emissions in the survey, which is substantially
greater than their output share.   The average VOC content for
small business products,  325 g/L,  is almost 75 percent higher
than the average VOC content for all surveyed products
combined, 186 g/L.
     Small business products have a higher VOC content than
the industry average for two possible reasons.  First,  small
businesses specialize in products that tend to be higher in
                             6-11

-------
                TABLE 6-2.  BASELINE VOC CONTENT
Size
Category*
All products
Small business
products
VOC
Emissions
(Mg)
344,059
21,431
Sales
(kL)
1,853,623
65,914
Average VOC
Content
(g/L)
186
325
a The survey had 116 respondents and 36 of those identified themselves as
  having under $10 million in annual sales.  Twelve survey respondents did
  not report company size.
Source:  Industry Insights.  Architectural and Industrial  Maintenance
        Surface Coatings  VOC Emissions Inventory Survey.  Prepared for
        National Paint and Coatings Association in cooperation with the
        AIM Regulatory Negotiation  Industry Caucus.  Final Draft Report.
        1993.

VOCs  because  of fundamental performance requirements  of the
products.   Second,  small businesses tend to produce higher
VOC-content products regardless  of  the  product category.  The
first reason  can be called a specialization effect and the
second reason a technology effect.
      Some  further  clarification  may be  in order.   Many of the
small companies in the architectural coatings industry are
regional firms whose product line is tailored to the  region in
which they operate and may tend  to  focus on smaller  "niche"
markets for which  larger manufacturers  may not choose to
devote manufacturing and marketing  resources.  Thus small
businesses may "specialize* in higher VOC coatings within
categories.   Therefore,  what is  referred to here as a
technology effect  {higher VOC  within categories in which small
and  large  manufacturers compete) may be caused by
specialization strategies.  In other words, some technology
effect may actually be due to  specialization within a
category.   With that caveat in mind, this report refers to
across-category factors as the specialization effect  and
within-category factors as the technology effect.
                               6-12

-------
     Distinguishing between  specialization and technology
factors underlying small  companies'  higher VOC content is
important in  terms of  the scope for regulatory flexibility.
To the extent that the specialization effect dominates, small
business impacts can potentially be addressed by modifying the
VOC limits  in the high VOC categories where small companies
specialize.   If the technology effect dominates, there is less
scope for modifying category limits to reduce impacts.
     The observed difference in average VOC content of small
businesses  and all products  was separated into the
specialization and technology effects using a simple
procedure.  First, a measure of the projected average VOC
content of  small business products was computed.  The
projected value was based on the distribution of small
business products among the  different product groups, weighted
by the average VOC content of each group.  This is a measure
of its specialization-based  VOC content:
                           N
                     Vs =  E  Vi1 • SiB .                     (6.1)
                          i=l
Here, V^  is the  industry average VOC content for all products
in product  category i,  SiB is the share of total small business
product quantity attributable to product category i, and N is
the total number of product  categories.8  The  separation of
the average VOC content difference into the two component
effects derives from the following equation:

      (VB - V1)    =     (VB - Vs)     +    (Vs  - V1)             (6.2)
     Difference   =     Technology +  Specialization
     in Average        Effect           Effect
     Content
     •s^ is not the small business share of total production in category
I,  but rather the contribution of category I to total small business
production.
                              6-13

-------
VB and V1 are, respectively, the  small business  and
industrywide VOC content averages.  The technology effect
quantifies the difference between the actual average VOC
content for small businesses and the specialization-adjusted
average.  The specialization effect quantifies  the difference
between the specialization-adjusted average for small
businesses and the overall industry average.
     Table 6-3 yields the computation of the Vs measure for
the small business products in the survey.71  The  computed  Vs
value is 261, meaning that one would expect an  average VOC
content of 261 g/L for the small business sector,  based purely
on the way their products are distributed among product groups
(i.e., their specialization).  Placing this value into Eq.
(6.2), along with the values for VB and V1 given above  (325 and
186), the breakdown is computed as follows:

               {Vs - V1)   =  (VB -  Vs)  +  (Vs  - V1)
               (325-186)  =  (325-261) +  (261-186)
                 139     =64      +75

     Approximately 54 percent of the 139 g/L difference
between the small business sector's VOC content average and
the industrywide average can be attributed to greater
specialization in high-VOC product categories  (specialization
effect), and the remaining 46 percent can be attributed to the
disproportionate presence of small business products in the
high-VOC end of the respective product categories (technology
effect).
     As indicated above, this finding has implications for the
feasibility of designing a TOS to minimize small  business
impacts.  Since small business producers are somewhat
concentrated in the higher VOC categories, as  indicated by the

                              6-14

-------
TABLE  6-3.
SPECIALIZATION-BASED AVERAGE VOC CONTENT:
   SMALL BUSINESS PRODUCTS'
Market
Segment
Number
12
12
1,2
11
1,2
1,2
9
3,4
1,2
7,8
3,4
5,6
13
13
12
7,8
7,8
7,8
3
12
7
13
1,2
Regulation
Category
Bond breakers
Concrete curing
compounds
Roof coatings
Traffic marking
paints
Nonflat,
exterior
Bituminous
coatings and
mastics
Lacquers
Flat, interior
Flat, exterior
Varnishes
Nonflat,
interior
Primers
Mastic texture
coatings
Industrial
maintenance
coatings
Metallic
pigmented
coatings
Stains,
semi transparent
Sealers
Waterproofing
sealers, clear
Quick dry
enamels
Graphic arts
coatings
Shellacs, clear
fc opaque
solventbome
Apurtenances
High performance
All
Products
Average VOC
(g/L)
NA
621
239
369
173
23
657
52
79
474
134
172
146
374
459
475
312
632
461
366
539
411
335
Share of Total
Small Business
Volume
NA
NA
0.3025
0.0857
0.0723
0.0675
0.0665
0.0639
0.0504
0.0482
0.0425
0.0422
0.0400
0.0395
0.0363
0.0091
0.0053
0.0048
0.0042
0.0038
0.0032
0.0030
0.0022
Share-
Weighted
Content
Factor

-------
      TABLE  6-3.   SPECIALIZATION-BASED AVERAGE VOC CONTENT:
                 SMALL BUSINESS  PRODUCTS'  (CONTINUED)
Market
Segment
Number
12
13
5,6
12
12
7,8
7,8
12
13
10
10
10
10
12
12
13
13
5,6

All
Products
Regulation Average VOC
Category (g/L)
Swimming pool
coatings
Sanding sealers
Undercoaters
Dry fog coatings
Antigraf f iti
coatings
Stains, opaque
Waterproofing
sealers, opaque
Pretreatment wash
primers
High- temperature
coatings
Below ground wood
preservatives
Clear wood
preservatives
Opaque wood
preservatives
Semi transparent
wood
preservatives
Form release
compounds
Multicolor
coatings
Fire-resistant/
retardant
coatings
Magnesite cement
coatings
Quick dry
primers,
undercoaters
Sums / averages
552
525
206
300
397
257
239
706
561
541
419
362
548
599
321
16
NA
439

Share of Total
Small Business
Volume
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
1
.0019
.0012
.0010
.0010
.0006
.0006
.0003
.0002
.0001
.0000
.0000
.0000
.0000
.0000
.0000
.0000
.0000
.0000
.0000
share -We i ghted
Content Factor
(g/L)
1.06
0.64
0.21
0.29
0.24
0.15
0.06
0.12
0.04
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
NA
0.00
260.87"
* Small businesses are defined as producing less  than $10 million  in architectural
  coatings products or less than $50 million in total sales.
b Specialized average VOC content equals the sum  of share-weighted content
  factors.
NA = Not available

Source:   Industry Insights.  Architectural  and  Industrial Maintenance Surface
         Coatings VOC Emissions  Inventory Survey.  Prepared for National Paint and
         Coatings Association  in cooperation with the AIM Regulatory Negotiation
         Industry Caucus.   Final Draft Report.  1993.


                                     6-16

-------
empirically sizable specialization effect, the regulation can
be designed to be somewhat less restrictive in categories with
high small business presence.  However, the effectiveness of
such an approach in mitigating small business impacts will be
limited by the fact that small business producers are also
concentrated in the high-VOC range of each product category.
An additional approach taken by the EPA was to evaluate
requests for additional categories to determine if a breakout
category for products in the higher-VOC range of a category
was needed.
     In 1993, the National Paint and Coatings Association
(NPCA) analyzed the VOC content limits that were under
discussion during the regulatory negotiation and found that
the projected emissions reduction from the small business
sector would be 19.65 percent of baseline emissions,  compared
to a projected 25 percent reduction for the industry.72  This
estimate provides some evidence of relief for small business
products under the standards under consideration at the time.
Moreover,  the final regulation is less stringent than the form
provided to NPCA in 1993.  Unfortunately,  data were not
available to recompute these estimates based on the current
content limits to see whether the proportional reduction from
the small business sector is still less than the current
overall reduction target of 20 percent.
6-2.3  Costs Associated With Regulatory Compliance
     As discussed in Section 2, compliance options that can be
quantitatively evaluated include product reformulation and the
payment of an exceedance fee.  The cost of a typical
reformulation is estimated at $87,000 per reformulation.73
This initial cost is converted to an annualized cost  of
                             6-17

-------
$14,573.£   The per-unit fee that producers can use as an
alternative compliance mechanism is computed as follows:

            fee = (VOC content - VOC limit) • rate,       (6.3)

VOC content is measured in grams per liter, and the  fee  rate
is paid on the grams per liter in excess of the limit.   The
fee rate is $2,500 per ton or $0.0028 per excess g/L (in .1996
dollars, $0.0024 when converted to 1991 dollars).  Total fee
payment per product simply equals the per-liter fee  multiplied
by total liters of production.
6.2.4  Reformulation Cost Impact Estimates
     Given the data from the survey and the VOC content  limits
set by the standard, the number of products produced by  small
businesses that exceed the VOC limits were identified.   The
number of potential reformulations was estimated by  applying
the content limits to the number of products reported by
category and VOC content in the survey to determine  the  number
exceeding the limit for each category.  Results are  reported
in Table 6-4.7*  An estimated 421 small business products in
the survey (42 percent) exceed the VOC content limits.   This
figure is slightly higher than the proportion of all surveyed
products that exceed the limit  (36 percent).  As established
in Section 2, approximately one-third of products  over the VOC
limit can costlessly comply with the regulation because  of
their similarity to the remaining over-the-limit products that
are being reformulated.  The remaining over-the-limit products
are referred to as "constrained" by the regulation and the sum
of the costless compliance products and under-the-limit
products as "unconstrained" by the regulation.
     'Details of the derivation of these estimates are presented in
Section 2 of this report.
                              6-18

-------
TABLE 6-4.   SMALL BUSINESS COSTS BY MARKET SEGMENT:  REFORMULATION OPTION ONLY"
Market
Segment Regulation
Number Category
12
12
1,2
11
1,2
1,2
ON 9
^ 3,4
10 1.2
7,8
3,4
5,6
13
13
12
7,8
7,8
Bondbreakers
Concrete curing
compounds
Roof coatings
Traffic marking
paints
Nonflat,
exterior
Bituminous
coatings and
mastics
Lacquers
Flat, interior
Flat, exterior
Varnishes
Nonflat,
interior
Primers
Mastic texture
coatings
Industrial
maintenance
coatings
Metallic
pigmented
coatings
Stains,
semitransparent
Sealers
Sales
(L)
NA
NA
19,938,649
5,649,468
4,764,963
4,450,233
4,383,825
4,214,045
3,320,278
3,177,311
2,801,665
2,779,526
2,636,665
2,602,918
2,389,690
601,978
350,434
Average
Price"
($/L)
$4.10
$4.10
$2.51
$1.45
$2.51
$2.51
$2.08
$2.21
$2.51
$2.66
$2.21
$2.44
$3.45
$3.45
$4.10
$2.66
$2.66
imputed
Revenues
($1991)
NA
NA
$50,046,010
$8,191,729
$11,960,057
$11,170,084
$9,118,356
$9,313,039
$8,333,897
$8,451,646
$6,191,679
$6,782,044
$9,096,494
$8,980,067
$9,797,729
$1,601,261
$932,155
Number of
Products
over
VOC Limit
0
0
13
14
70
1
5
13
34
33
26
79
1
33
19
12
2
Number of
Constrained
Products'
0
0
9
9
47
1
3
9
23
22
17
53
1
22
13
8
1
Total Cost of
Reformulating
Constrained Reform Cost
Products* per Unit
($1991) ($/L)
$0
$0
$126,273
$135,987
$679,933
$9,713
$48,567
$126,273
$330,253
$320,540
$252,547
$767,353
$9,713
$320,540
$184,553
$116,560
$19,427
NA
NA
$0.01
$0.02
$0.14
$0.00
$0.01
$0.03
$0.10
$0.10
$0.09
$0.28
$0.00
$0.12
$0.08
$0.19
' $0.06
Reformulation
Cost /Revenues
(%)
NA
NA
0.3%
1.7%
5.7%
0.1%
0.5%
1.4%
4.0%
3.8%
4.1%
11. 3*
0.1%
3.6%
1.9%
7.3%
2.1%
                                                                                (continued)

-------
TABLE 6-4.
SMALL BUSINESS COSTS BY  MARKET SEGMENT:
                       (CONTINUED)
REFORMULATION OPTION ONLY"
Market
Segment Regulation
Number Category
7,8
3
12
7
13
? 1.2
^ 12
O
13
5.6
12
12
7.8
7,8
12
13
Waterproofing
sealers, clear
Quick dry
enamels
Graphic arts
coatings
Shellacs, clear
& opaque
solventborne
Apurtenances
High performance
Swimming pool
coatings
Sanding sealers
Undercoaters
Dry fog coatings
Antigraffiti
coatings
Stains, opaque
Waterproof ing
sealers, opaque
Pre treatment
wash primers
High- temperature
coatings
Sales
(L)
318,046
279,893
251,343
210,817
200,473
144,958
126,358
80,170
66,427
63,187
40,060
38,668
16,726
11,272
4,383
Average
Price"
($/L)
$2.66
$3.18
$4.10
$3.06
$3.45
$2.51
$4.10
$3.45
$2.44
$4.10
$4.10
$2.66
$2.66
$4.10
$3.45
Imputed
Revenues
($1991)
$846,
$890,
$1,030,
$645,
$691,
$363,
$518,
$276,
$162,
$259,
$164,
$102,
$44,
$46,
$15,
002
060
506
100
630
844
070
587
081
066
248
856
491
214
121
Number of
Products
over
VOC Limit
9
9
8
0
5
12
0
1
3
6
1
6
2
4
0
Total Cost of
Reformulating
Number of Constrained
Constrained Products'
Products0 ($1991)
6
6
5
0
3
8
0
1
2
4
1
4
1
3
0
$87,
$87,
$77,

$48,
$116,
$9,
$29,
$58,
$9,
$58,
$19,
$38,

420
420
707
$0
567
560
$0
713
140
280
713
280
427
853
$0
Reform Cost
per Unit
$0.27
$0.31
$0.31
$0.00
$0.24
$0.80
$0.00
$0.12
$0.44
$0.92
$0.24
$1.51
$1.16
$3.45
$0.00
Reformulation
Cost /Revenues
10.3%
9.8%
7.5%
0.0%
7.0%
32.0%
0.0%
3.5%
ia.o%
22.5%
5.9%
56.7%
43.7%
•4.1%
0.0%
                                                                               (continued)

-------
            TABLE 6-4.
SMALL BUSINESS  COSTS BY MARKET SEGMENT:
                               (CONTINUED)
REFORMULATION  OPTION  ONLY8
to

Market
Segment
Number
10


10

10

10


12

12

13


13

5,6





Regulation
Category
Below ground
wood
preservatives
Clear wood
preservatives
Opaque wood
pr eservat ives
Semi transparent
wood
preservatives
Form release
compounds
Multicolor
coatings
Fire-resistant/
retardant
coatings
Hagnesite
coatings
Quick dry
primers,
undercoaters
Total /Average


Sales
(L)
0


0

0

0


0

0

0


0

0


65,914,429

Average
Price"
(S/L)
$1.45


$1.45

$1.45

$1.45


$4.10

$4.10

$3.45


$3.45

$2.44


$2.52

Imputed
Revenues
($1991)
$0


$0

$0

$0


$0

$0

$0


$0

$0


$166,022,123
Number of
Products
over
VOC Limit
0


0

0

0


0

0

0


0

0


421

Number of
Constrained
Products0
0


0

0

0


0

0

0


0

0


281
Total Cost of
Reformulating
Constrained
Products'1
($1991)
$0


$0

$0

$0


$0

$0

$0


$0

$0


$4,089,313

Reform Cost
per Unit
($/L)
$0.00


$0.00

$0.00

$0.00


$0.00

$0.00

$0.00


$0.00

$0.00


$0.06

Reformulation
Cost /Revenues
(%)
0.0%


0.0%

0.0%

0.0%


0.0%

0.0%

0.0%


0.0%

0.0%


2.5%
     NA * not available
     *  Small businesses ar« defined as producing  less than $10 million in architectural coatings products or less than  $50 million in
        total sales.
     b  Average prices are taken from Section 2, and a weighted average is used when the product category belongs in two market
        segments.
     c  Number of  products over the limit multiplied by two-thirds to  represent the portion that potentially undergo major
        reformulation.  Numbers in table are rounded.
     d  Annual!zed cost of reformulations is the number of products facing reformulation multiplied by  the annualized major
        reformulation cost estimate per product of  $14,573 (details in Section 2).
     Source:  Industry Insights.  Architectural and Industrial  Maintenance Surface  Coatings VOC  Emissions Inventory  Survey.   Prepared
              for National  Paint and Coatings Association  in cooperation with the AIM Regulatory Negotiation Industry Caucus.   Final
              Draft Report.   1993.

-------
     Less  than  10  percent  of  the small business products in
the sanding sealers, mastic texture coatings,  and bituminous
categories will be constrained by the regulation.  Swimming
pool coatings,  shellacs, and  high-temperature coatings
produced by the small  business sector will require no
reformulations.  Traffic paints,  roof coatings, and varnishes
are all relatively high-volume categories in which over
40 percent of the  surveyed small business products are
constrained by  the VOC limits.
     6.2.4.1  Small Business  Impacts Under "Reformulation-
Only* Option.   In  this section,  the estimation of the total
and per-unit annualized compliance costs for small producers
in each product category with reformulation as the only
compliance option  is described.   As with the impacts presented
in Section 2, the  "reformulation-only" scenario gives the
upper bound of  regulatory  costs.   The effect of cost-reducing
strategies  (fee and withdrawal)  is considered in the next
subsection.
     The annualized $14,573 estimate of the cost per
reformulation was  multiplied  by the number of products
constrained by  the regulation (all products over the limit
less the one-third that can costlessly comply).  Table 6-4
lists the  cost  estimates.  These costs can be compared with
revenue information to gauge  the relative impact of the
regulation on small businesses.
     To compute product revenue,  the analysis uses average
price per  liter for each category (see Sections 2 and 3) for
the market segment in  which the category is classified.0  The
cost of reformulation  as a percentage of revenues was computed
using the  estimated cost of reformulation divided by the
     "Where a coating category could not be separated into waterborne and
solventborne market segments (categories in market segments 1 through 8),  a
weighted average of the two prices was used.
                              6-22

-------
imputed revenues for each product category.  Ideally, costs
would be calculated for each firm affected by the regulation
and compared to the firm's revenues as a firm-specific measure
of impacts.  Then,  these measures could be used to determine
the number and percentage of firms exceeding certain
cost/revenue threshold values,  e.g., 1 percent or 3 percent.
What constitutes a significant impact varies, depending on
typical profit rates and other industry-specific factors.
     Unfortunately, the product-level survey data used to
estimate costs did not identify the firms that produced each
surveyed product.  Therefore, it was not possible to estimate
costs at the firm level.  In lieu of the firm-level measures,
the analysis calculated cost/revenue affects per market
segment (in Table 6-4) and the average cost/revenue ratio per
small company using summary totals from the small business
component of the survey (in Table 3-5).
6.2.5  Cost Impacts Across Market Segments
     The data presented in Table 6-4 illustrate a number of
scenarios pertaining to potential small business impacts of
the regulation under a reformulation-only response scenario.
Key phenomena indicated by the data are examined below.
     Based on the survey data,  roof coatings is the largest
quantity and highest revenue category for small businesses.
For small business roof coatings,  43 percent of the individual
products will be constrained; however, the cost of
reformulation as a percentage of sales is relatively small,
less than 1 percent.
     Categories with cost/revenue ratios in excess of
10 percent are highlighted in bold in Table 6-4.  The three
highest impact categories are opaque waterproofing sealers
(43.7 percent), opaque stains (56.7 percent), and pretreatment
                             6-23

-------
wash primers  (84.1 percent).11  In each case,  the large impacts
result from the fact that  the  average product volumes are very
small  (e.g.,  just 2,800  liters per  product in pretreatment
wash primers).  This provides  further evidence of the point
made throughout the report that  the impact on small volume
products is potentially  large  because of the fixed cost nature
of reformulation.  Obviously the impacts would be dramatic if
these products were forced to  reformulate.  However, the fee
option provides relief from these high impacts.  Therefore,
the highest proportional impacts estimated in Table 6-4 would
not occur with the fee as  a compliance option.  If, for
instance, an  average size  pretreatment wash primer
(2,800 liters) were 100  g/L over the limit for the category,
then the total fee payment would be (100 g/L) • $0.0022/g •
2,800  1 = $616.  Clearly the producer's cost-minimizing
compliance  option would  be to  choose the fee rather than incur
the annualized reformulation cost of almost $15,000.  As a
result, the 84.1 percent figure  greatly overstates the true
cost impact for the prototypical pretreatment wash primer
product.  Given the fee  amount just computed, the figure would
be closer to  5 percent of  revenues for that category.  Similar
arguments can be made  for the  other categories representing
the highest impacts in Table 6-4.  Further quantitative
evidence of the cost  savings from the fee  (and withdrawal)
compliance  options  is presented below.
     Antigraffiti  coatings present quite a different  small
business  impact outcome.  Small businesses represent  almost
the entire  market  but produce  small quantities  in relation to
other  coating categories and generate lower revenues.  Only
one product requires  reformulation under the VOC limits, but
      "This analysis is based on the interim standards presented in
 Section 2.  As indicated in Section 7,  the content limit for opaque
 waterproofing was raised in the final standards.  Thus, the cost impact for
 that category would likely be lower than indicated here.
                               6-24

-------
the cost of reformulating that product would represent about 6
percent of revenues in the category.
6.2.6  Average Cost Impacts for Small Company
     For the small business segment of the architectural
coatings industry overall, 42 percent of the products are over
the VOC content limits, and 28 percent are expected to undergo
reformulation, pay an exceedance fee, or exit.  The total
annualized cost for the sample of small businesses in the
survey under the reformulation-only scenario is $4.1 million.
The average cost per unit is $0.06 per liter.
     Table 6-5 compares small firm and industry averages for
revenues, number of products, and reformulation costs.75  Small
businesses on average manufacture approximately one-third
fewer products than the industry average.  On average, small
firms have fewer constrained products than the industry
average, but they comprise a slightly larger percentage of
total number of products, 28 percent, as compared to
23 percent for the industry.  Similarly, small business
reformulation costs as a percentage of revenues are higher at
2.5 percent than the industry at roughly 0.4 percent.
     In response to concerns expressed in the public comment
period about the limited coverage of firms used to assess
small business impacts, EPA obtained a list identifying small
businesses in the industry and gathered data on total revenues
and employment for these firms.  However, without specific
information on the number of products produced and their VOC
content, there is no method to determine the number of
products for each firm that would incur reformulation costs.
Unfortunately, assigning the average costs for a small firm
presented here (based on 7.8 noncompliant products)  cannot
produce a meaningful evaluation of the distribution of small
firms' impacts.  This occurs because the calculation of
cost/revenue ratios for these firms varies the denominator
                             6-25

-------
      TABLE 6-5.   AVERAGE  REGULATORY  IMPACT BY  FIRM SIZE-
                  *REFORMULATION-ONLY* SCENARIO"

Revenue" ($1991)
Number of products"
Number of products facing major
reformulation0
Annualized reformulation cost* ($1991)
Ratio of annualized reformulation
cost to revenues (percent)
Industry
Average
38,990,000
42.4
9.9
144,272
0.4

Small Firm
Average
4,614,000
27.5
7.8
113,669
2.5

•  The survey has 116 respondents and 36 of those identified themselves as
  having under $10 million in annual sales.   Twelve survey respondents did
  not report company size.
b  Data for revenues and products per firm were based on data reported in
  Table 6-1.  The number of products per firm is based on the total number
  of products for which quantity data are available.
c  This number represents two-thirds of the products over the 1998 TOS.
  Industry experts estimate that approximately two-thirds of the products
  with VOC contents exceeding the TOS limits face a 'major* reformulation.
d  Annualized cost of reformulation is the number of major reformulations
  multiplied by the annualized reformulation cost estimate per product of
  $14,573 ($1991).

Source:  Industry Insights.  Architectural and Industrial Maintenance
        Surface Coatings VOC Emissions Inventory Survey.  Prepared for
        National Paint and Coatings Association in cooperation with the
        AIM Regulatory Negotiation Industry Caucus.  Final Draft Report.
        1993.


(revenues)  by  firm, but  the numerator (compliance costs)

remain fixed as those represented  by the model  (average)  firm.

Using this method, the estimated impacts would, by definition,

be  relatively  larger for firms with smaller  revenues.

However, it does not necessarily follow that  a firm with low

revenues would have the  same level of reformulation costs as a

firm with larger revenues;  such an analysis would therefore

overstate impacts on the smallest  firms.  Therefore,  for the

final rule EPA uses the  data from  the 36 firms in the survey

to  provide a representative look at model company small

business impacts as described above.
                                 6-26

-------
6.2.7  Potential Factors Mitigating  Small Business Impacts:
       Exceedance Fee, Withdrawal, and Tonnage Exemption
     6.2.7.1  Fee and Withdrawal  Options.  As discussed in
Section 2, a product's output  level  affects the choice between
reformulating the product  and  paying an exceedance fee.  Since
the cost of reformulation  is a fixed cost  (i.e., it is
independent of output level),  the average reformulation cost
per unit of output  falls as output levels increase.  However,
the exceedance fee  per unit of output is constant with respect
to the output levels and the fixed costs of the fee
(recordkeeping) are relatively small.  Thus, the fee is more
likely to be chosen by small-volume  producers, all else equal.
Because the fee will be more cost-effective only for
lower-volume products and  lower-excess VOC categories,
allowing the fee option should have  a relatively small impact
on variation from the aggregate emissions reduction targets as
long as the fee assessment rate is not set at an
inappropriately low level.  The results presented in Section 2
support this point.  Therefore, the  fee option provides
increased flexibility for  small businesses by placing an upper
limit on the per-unit costs of complying with the regulation,
without significantly jeopardizing VOC emissions reduction
targets.
     It is not possible to directly  conduct a best-response
(least-cost) analysis of the fee/reformulation decisions for
the small business  segment of  the  survey because of
insufficiently detailed VOC data on  small businesses.
However, the results of the best-response analysis in
Section 2 can be employed to indirectly measure the effect of
alternative compliance strategies  on the relative size of
small business impacts.
     Based on survey data for  the  small business segment,  the
average small firm has 27.5 products, 7.8 of which would be
                             6-27

-------
constrained by  the regulation.   Table 6-6 divides the  average
small company's number of constrained products into  three
compliance categories:  reformulation,  fee, and withdrawal.
The average number of products  selecting each strategy is
based on the  average percentage  of  all constrained products in
the survey  (small company and large)  that select each  option.
        TABLE  6-6.   AVERAGE REGULATORY  IMPACT FOR SMALL
               COMPANIES-"BEST-RESPONSE" SCENARIO
Compliance
Strategy
Reformulate
Fee
Withdrawal
Total
Average percent
Percent of
All
Constrained
Survey
Products
Selecting
Option
60.5%
35.5%
4.0%
100.0%
of sales
"Expected"
Number of
Products
Selecting
Strategy3
4.7
2.8
0.3
7.8

Average
Compliance
Cost per
Product
(1991 $)
14,573
7,197b
12,705°
11,879

Compliance
Cost
(1991 $)
68,767
19, 936
3, 955
92, 658
2.0%
a Equals average number of constrained products for small companies (7.!
  multiplied by percentage of  all constrained products in the survey
  selecting each strategy.
b Average fee cost computed by taking the average fee rate ($0.084/L),
  multiplying by the average size per small company product (65,914 L),
  and adding the recordkeeping cost per product of $590.
c Equals the average value of  foregone profits for the 46 surveyed
  products that select the fee as the best-response strategy.
This is  expected to be a conservative assumption  because small
volume products produced by  small  businesses are  more likely
to select  the fee option to  reduce regulation costs.
Compliance costs were estimated by multiplying the  number of
products  in each category by the per-product cost of  that
strategy.   Summed across all products,  the per-company
compliance costs fall to about  $88,000, which is  about
23 percent less than the cost per  company  under  the
reformulation-only scenario.  The  average cost ratio  under the
                               6-28

-------
best-response scenario is 2.0 percent.   Considering that small
companies may be even more likely to select the fee than the
survey population at large,  the cost reductions may be even
greater than those estimated in Table 6-6.
     The results presented in Tables 6-5 and 6-6 together
indicate that, while the average impact on small companies is
expected to be larger than the average impact on all
producers, the alternative strategies to reformulation,
particularly the fee option, can reduce the small company
impacts substantially.
     6.2.7.2  Tonnage Exemption.  As an alternative to the fee
options of reformulation, fee, or withdrawal, the EPA will
allow a phased tonnage exemption for architectural producers.
Affected firms will be allowed to exempt a total of 23 Mg of
VOC emissions from control responsibilities through
December 31, 2000, 18 Mg in 2001, and 9 Mg in 2002 and beyond.
These tonnage exemption levels differ from the fee in two
ways.  First, the exempt emissions can be applied across all
noncompliant products a firm produces,  whereas the fee is
assessed individually for each noncompliant product for which
the fee is selected.  Second, the exempt emissions that are
granted are the total emissions of the product rather than
just those in excess of the content limit.  Thus, a firm must
coordinate the VOC levels and reguirements of all facilities
and products to determine which ones will be produced under
the tonnage exemption.
     The tonnage exemption allows some low-volume products
relief from reformulation costs that can be difficult to
recover from the small amount of revenue generated by a
low-volume product.  Both the exceedance fee alternative and
the tonnage exemption are compliance options aimed at
addressing the potential issue of "niche markets" in which
low-volume products exist for which it may not be
                              6-29

-------
cost-effective  for either the manufacturer or  resin supplier
to develop  a  lower VOC formulation.
     The EPA  lacks data to directly evaluate the  economic
impact of the tonnage exemption.  It is likely, however,  that
many of the products  covered under the tonnage exemption  might
otherwise be  subject  to the exceedance fee because  both
provisions  are  most applicable to the smallest volume
products1.   Therefore,  the  tonnage  exemption provision  is not
likely to further  curtail emissions reductions much beyond
what is curtailed  by  the fee option.  However,  to the  extent
that it supplants  the fee as a firm's compliance  option,  it
will reduce the financial impact of the regulation  on  that
firm.  For  example, if 9 Mg of VOCs exempted from regulation
represents  3.6  Mg  of  exceedance (assuming an exceedance rate
on over-limit products of 40 percent),  then the firm subject
to the tonnage  exemption can forego 3.6 Mg worth  of fee
payments which,  at $2,200 per MG (in 1991 dollars),  translates
to an impact  reduction of $7,920 per firm.  If this is  applied
to the roughly  500 firms in the architectural  coatings
industry, the maximum potential reduction in aggregate
producer impacts is estimated to be about $4 million.
However, it cannot be directly determined whether each  firm
would be able to take advantage of the tonnage exemption  and
incur these savings.   One should also note that,  while  these
represent potential savings to producers, these are offset  by
reductions  in fee  receipts by the government sector.  Thus,  to
the extent  that the tonnage exemption merely substitutes  for
the fee, the  substitution has not affected the net  social cost
of the regulation.
     1     EPA recognizes that a few products on the margin that would be
reformulated if the fee  was the only alternative option, may now use a
combination of the tonnage exemption and fee  if it is determined to be the
firm's least-cost compliance option. To the  extent that this will occur,
there will be a minimal  effect on additional  foregone emission reductions
when the exemption is considered as a compliance strategy.

                              6-30

-------
     The tonnage exemption may also serve in lieu of small
product withdrawals.  In this case, the tonnage exemption
would curtail some emission reductions.  However, given the
relatively few products projected for withdrawal and the small
volumes involved,  the effect on VOC emissions would likely be
small.
     While seeking ways to mitigate the impacts of the
regulation for small manufacturers, the EPA recognizes that
the two different approaches discussed here, the fee option
and small product tonnage exemption, have different
implications for the marginal incentives for VOC reductions.
Although the fee option continues to provide incentive to
reformulate the small niche products because marginal
reductions in VOC content will reduce the per- unit fee paid,
a tonnage exemption would provide no such incentive.

6.3  REGULATORY ALTERNATIVES TO REDUCE IMPACTS

     The Agency has engaged in extensive dialogue with both
large and small businesses over the 8-year period of
development of the final rule.  The Agency has sought input
from small businesses through a regulatory negotiation,
meetings between EPA and small businesses, and SBA review of
the proposal.  Based on this involvement, the EPA incorporated
many of the suggested changes and designed the proposed rule
to address concerns about potential impacts on small
businesses.  Specifically, coating categories and VOC content
limits were selected to account for niche products in which
smaller manufacturers have a disproportionate presence.  In
addition, to evaluate whether further steps were still needed
to accommodate niche market coatings, the Agency requested
that commenters identify any additional specialty coatings
that  could not comply with the proposed VOC content
                             6-31

-------
requirements.   The Agency also requested comment on whether to
include several other compliance options to provide
flexibility and reduce the burden for small businesses.  This
section presents a summary of significant issues raised by
public comment on those compliance options and the Agency's
consideration of those compliance options as well as other
provisions in the rule to mitigate rule impacts on small
businesses and preservation of niche markets.  The response to
comments document entitled "National Volatile Organic Compound
Emission Standards for Architectural Coatings—Background for
Promulgated Standards," EPA-453/R-95-009b, contains more
detailed summaries of the comments and the EPA's response.
     The EPA considered the following compliance options and
other measures to mitigate impacts of the rule on small
businesses:
     •   selection of VOC content limits and coating
         categories;
     •   low-volume exemption option;
     •   exceedance fee compliance option;
     •   extended compliance time for small businesses;
     •   compliance variance for cases where compliance would
         result in economic hardship;  and
     •   selection of recordkeeping and reporting
         requirements.

Based on review of comments and further analysis of the
effects of the rule,  the EPA has elected to incorporate a
number of the above compliance options and other measures into
the final rule  to avoid unnecessary impacts on small
businesses.   This section presents the results of the EPA's
final regulatory flexibility analysis, which evaluates the
alternative measures considered to mitigate the impacts of the
rule on small businesses.  This discussion incorporates the

                              6-32

-------
results of the economic impact analysis presented earlier in
this section as well as the Agency's policy considerations and
other information used in selecting the compliance options and
other measures to mitigate the impacts of the rule on small
businesses.
6.3.1  Selection of VQC Content Limits and Coating Categories
     In developing the proposed rule, the EPA recognized that
it may not be economical for some manufacturers to reformulate
certain lower-volume products.  Rather than exempting these
lower-volume products, the EPA proposed the VOC content limits
in the upper range of VOC content limits in existing state
rules for these categories.  For categories for which no state
standards exist, the EPA included the categories in the
architectural coating rule based on discussions with industry
representatives and end-user groups, petitions from
stakeholders prior to proposal, and public comments from
companies providing support for inclusion of the categories
and a suggested VOC content limit.  In discussion of the
proposed low-volume exemption, the EPA also requested that
commenters submit detailed information on any specialty
coatings that would not comply with the proposed VOC content
limits and that cannot be cost-effectively reformulated.  The
proposal indicated that the EPA would consider whether to
develop additional categories for newly identified niche
categories or to provide a categorical exemption for the
specialty coating.76'77
     As a result of information submitted by commenters, the
Agency has added seven new categories to the final rule to
address specific groups of specialty coatings that were
identified through public comment.  Also, based on new
information the VOC content limits were increased in the final
rule for four categories.  Available information indicates
that the final rule includes VOC content limits at levels that
                             6-33

-------
recognize the limited potential for reformulation of specialty
niche products and sets VOC contents at the upper range for
the particular type of product.  The EPA established special
categories and limits for niche products and established
higher-than-proposed VOC content limits for niche product
categories where commenters submitted sufficient supporting
information.  As a result,  the final VOC limits for these
categories are unlikely to require manufacturers to
reformulate many products.   The specific changes are
identified in Section 7 of this document.
6.3.2  Low-Volume Exemption Option
     The Agency requested comment on the concept of a low-
volume compliance exemption option.78  In the proposal preamble
this exemption was described as a compliance option under
which "any manufacturer or importer may request an exemption
from the VOC levels in table 1 for specialized coating
products that are manufactured or imported in quantities less
than a specified number of gallons per year."  The Agency
specifically requested comment on exemptions ranging from
1,000 to 5,000 gallons of product per year.  The exemption, as
described in the proposal,  could be used by a manufacturer for
multiple products, provided that each product was manufactured
in quantities less than the cutoff level.  As described in the
proposal preamble, the manufacturer would be required to
submit a request for the exemption and document that the
product(s) for which the exemption was requested "served a
specialized use which cannot be cost-effectively replaced with
another, lower VOC product."  The EPA recognizes that small
businesses who produce products with limited volume will
benefit most from an exemption of this type.
     Seventeen commenters supported some form of a low-volume
exemption, and four commenters opposed such an exemption.
Commenters supporting the low-volume exemption suggested
                              6-34

-------
cutoffs ranging from 100,000 gallons per product down to
1,000 gallons per product.  Commenters opposed to the
low-volume exemption argued that it was subject to abuse
because of difficulty in defining what is a "product."  These
commenters believed that this compliance option would provide
an incentive for companies to develop purportedly "new"
specialty products to keep selling noncompliant coatings.
     Based on the arguments presented by commenters about the
need for some type of exemption for very low-volume specialty
products for which it is not cost-effective for either the
manufacturer or the resin supplier to devote time and
resources to reformulation, an exemption is included in the
final rule to accommodate these types of products.  Although
in the proposal preamble, the exemption was described in terms
of a per-product exemption at a level between 1,000 and
5,000 gallons annually,  commenters highlighted the potential
problems with this type of provision.  Therefore, the final
rule contains a variation on the low-volume exemption approach
described at proposal.   Specifically, a VOC tonnage exemption
is provided in the final rule.  This approach continues to
accommodate the needs of small businesses, niche markets, and
specialty products, as did the proposed low-volume exemption;
but it more effectively limits the VOC emissions resulting
from the exemption.  It is expected that this provision will
provide more benefit to small businesses than large
businesses.
     Under the VOC tonnage exemption, each manufacturer can
exempt a total of 23 megagrams (25 tons) of VOC in the period
of time from the compliance date through December 31, 2000;
18 megagrams (20 tons)  in the year 2001, and 9 megagrams
(10 tons)  for the year 2002 and for each year thereafter.
Since some corporations have multiple companies and/or
divisions,  an architectural coatings manufacturer or importer
                             6-35

-------
is defined in the rule to mean the parent company and not each
individual company, subsidiary, or division.  Thus, if a
corporation  (parent company) has several subsidiaries or
divisions that manufacture coatings, only one exemption per
parent company will be allowed annually.  This provision is
structured in this manner to avoid sacrificing VOC emission
reductions and to be equitable to manufacturers.  For the
purposes of the tonnage exemption, the manufacturer or
importer calculates VOC tonnage by multiplying the total sales
volume in liters by the "in the can" VOC content of the
coating in grams per liter of coating including any water or
exempt compounds.  The "in the can" VOC content must include
consideration of the maximum thinning recommended by the
manufacturer.  In the following examples, g/L (or Ib/gal) is
an abbreviation for grams (or pounds) of VOC per liter (or
gallon) of coating, including water and exempt compounds at
the manufacturer's maximum recommendation for thinning.  For
example, under this exemption in the second year a
manufacturer could exempt 38,300 liters  (8,000 gallons) of a
600 g/L (5 Ib/gal) coating.

       51bs/gallon * 8,000 gallons = 40,000 Ibs or 20 tons

     Alternatively, a manufacturer could exempt 18,939 liters
(4,000 gallons)  of an 800 g/L  (6.67 Ib/gal)  coating plus
13,731 liters (3,625 gallons)  of a 550 g/L  (4.58 Ib/gal)
coating.
        [(6.67 Ibs/gal *  4,000)+(4.58 Ibs/gal * 2,900)]  =
                      40, 000 Ibs or 20 tons

A manufacturer can exempt any combination of coatings and
volumes as long as the total emissions from these products do
not exceed 23 Mg  (25 tons)  from the compliance date through
                             6-36

-------
December 31, 2000; 18 Mg  (20 tons) in the year 2001; and 9 Mg
(10 tons) in the year 2002 and each year thereafter.
     The tonnage limits would exempt no more than 1.5 to
2 percent of the total expected emission reductions from
architectural coatings in the first year the standard is in
effect.  The 9 Mg  (10 ton) per-year exemption that goes into
effect in the year 2002 will provide adequate flexibility for
future needs, while effectively limiting emissions due to the
exemption.   For firms with VOC content around 600 g/1 (5
Ib/gal), the exemption could apply to 4,000 gallons total
across all of the firm's products. .As is demonstrated in the
calculation of potential cost savings, the exemption can
provide significant relief to small firms or niche market
products by reducing prossible fee payments.  However,  since
it applies to all products of a firms, it is substantially
lower than the 1,000 to 5,000 gallon per product exemption
considered at proposal.
     This exemption differs from the low-volume exemption in
the proposal preamble in the following ways:
     (1)   The EPA changed the exemption from a per-product
          basis to a per-manufacturer basis.  This was  done to
          avoid the difficulty of defining a "product"  and to
          avoid the related potential for abuse by
          manufacturers  in designating products for exemption.
     (2)   The EPA changed the exemption level from gallons of
          coating to tons of VOC.   This change was made  for
          two primary reasons.   First, it provides an
          incentive for  manufacturers to reduce the VOC
          content of the coatings for which they claim  this
          exemption.   For example,  with a 5,000 gallon
          exemption,  the manufacturer could exempt 5,000
          gallons whether the product was 850 g/L or 200 g/L.
          With a tonnage exemption,  however, the VOC content
          in each can of coating counts toward the allotted
          exemption.   Therefore,  if the manufacturer reduces
          the VOC content of the coating it wishes to exempt,
         more gallons of that  coating could be sold under the
          exemption.   Second,  the  choice of VOC tonnage
          instead of gallons of coating for the exemption

                             6-37

-------
          alters the exemption from an unknown loss of
          emission reductions to a cap on tons exempted per
          manufacturer.   Therefore,  this change serves to
          place an upper bound on the emission reductions that
          are lost through this exemption,  which allows the
          Agency to better estimate its anticipated impact.

     (3)   The exemption  is reduced over time.   The ratcheting
          down of the tonnage exemption from 23 Mg (25 tons),
          to 18 Mg (20 tons), and then to 9 Mg (10 tons)
          provides a strong incentive to manufacturers using
          the exemption  to continue to seek ways to reduce the
          VOC content of their coatings.  This exemption is
          intended to provide additional time for
          manufacturers  to reformulate coatings,  and provide
          some relief in the long run for small volume
          producers.

6.3.3  Exceedance Fee Compliance Option

     The EPA requested comment on whether to include an

exceedance fee option for use as a compliance alternative to

meeting the VOC content  limits in the proposed rule.79  This

option was designed to provide compliance flexibility and set

the fee rate high enough to provide an economic incentive for

reformulation.  The proposed fee rate was $0.0028 per gram

($2,500 per ton) of VOC  in excess of the applicable VOC
content limit multiplied by the amount of coating produced.
The EPA also requested comment on the appropriateness of the

proposed fee rate and the recordkeeping and reporting
requirements associated  with the exceedance fee compliance

option.
     Public comment on the concept of this option varied

widely.  Some commenters, including small businesses and

national coating manufacturers trade associations, were

supportive of the concept because it provided compliance

flexibility.  Some of these commenters supported the concept

under the condition that the option would not be accompanied

by burdensome recordkeeping requirements.  Other groups of

commenters opposed inclusion of this option because they
                             6-38

-------
thought that it could disrupt the market (increase prices),
that it would be difficult to enforce,  or that it was
unnecessary because the proposed limits were not hard to
achieve.  For a more complete description of the comments on
this option, see Section 2.4.1 of the Architectural Coating
Regulation BID.
     Careful evaluation of all of the comments and discussions
with the SBA led the Agency to include the exceedance fee
option in the final rule.  Under this approach, manufacturers
and importers have the option of paying a fee, based on the
extent to which VOC content limits are exceeded, instead of
achieving the VOC content limits in the rule.  The fee is
calculated at a rate of $0.0028 per gram ($2,500 per ton), in
1996 dollars, of VOC in excess of the applicable VOC content
limit, multiplied by the volume of coating produced.  This
option is included in the rule for several reasons.  The
exceedance fee option will provide transition time for those
manufacturers that need additional time to obtain lower-VOC
technologies.  The exceedance fee option provides long-term
flexibility and a less costly compliance option than
reformulation for both small and large manufacturers selling
very low-volume specialty coatings where the cost of
reformulation may be prohibitive compared to the potential
profit, thus enabling manufacturers to continue to make these
products available to consumers.  The exceedance fee option is
significantly less burdensome for manufacturers than the
proposed compliance variance provision, which has not been
retained in the final rule.  However, contrary to some
comments received, costs resulting from the exceedance fees
will likely generally motivate manufacturers over time to
develop high performance products with low-VOC content.
     Some commenters believed that the exceedance fee will
disrupt the marketplace, shifting business among companies.
                              6-39

-------
However, since the fee will probably be used primarily for the
manufacture of low-volume specialty coatings, which are driven
by demand from consumers, it is not likely that the demand
from these markets would be significant enough to provide any
incentive for manufacturers to shift to these products.  The
impacts to the market are lower with the fee than they would
be if reformulation was the only option available for
producers, because the fee reduces the number of potential
product withdrawals and reduces the net social cost.  Raising
the VOC content limits, as suggested by some of the
commenters,  in lieu of offering the fee could significantly
undermine the emissions reduction objectives of the rule.  The
fee provides some flexibility to producers of low-volume
products, or products that are only slightly above the VOC
content limit of the standard,  who may find it prohibitive to
incur the largely fixed cost of reformulation.  Because
products for which manufacturers will choose to pay the fee
would tend to represent a small portion of the national VOC
emissions from architectural coatings, the fee option itself
would not significantly undermine emission reduction
objectives.   However, raising the VOC content limits in the
rule to accommodate all low-volume products would negate the
VOC emission reductions from all these products.  The fee also
provides continued incentive for producers to reduce VOC
content until they achieve the VOC content limits in the rule.
     With regard to concerns about enforcement of the
exceedance fee, the recordkeeping and reporting requirements
are designed to ensure compliance with this option.  Any
violations of the recordkeeping and reporting or any other
requirements could result in enforcement actions and the
possibility of penalties.
     The estimated cost for reporting and recordkeeping of the
fee provision at a small company using the exceedance fee
                             6-40

-------
provisions for eight products is approximately $5,000 per year
(see Table 6-5).   This cost represents the cost to maintain
the records of the VOC content and the total volume
manufactured or imported for which the exceedance fee option
is used as well as the preparation of the annual report for
payment of the exceedance fee.  Assuming $5 million of sales
revenue as a midpoint estimate for small companies in the $0
to 10 million range, fee recordkeeping costs would be
approximately 0.1 percent of sales revenue, which is not a
significant burden.
     Price increases on fee-paying products will cause some
consumer substitution to nonfee-paying (lower-VOC) products.
For some products, it may not be profitable to reformulate or
pay the fee, so firms may consider withdrawing the product
from the market.   These phenomena are explicitly modeled
elsewhere in this document.  However, the premise of the fee
is that it internalizes the  (public)  environmental cost of VOC
emissions into the private cost of the good.  Therefore, if
some consumers substitute away from the now higher-priced
fee-paying product, it reflects the fact that they are not
willing to pay the "full" cost of consuming the higher—VOC
products.  This is the fundamental purpose of market-based
incentives for environmental protection.
     6.3.3.1  Exceedance Fee Rate.  Several commenters also
submitted comments on the proposed exceedance fee rate of
$0.0028 per gram of VOC in excess of the applicable VOC
content limit.  Some of these commenters thought that the fee
rate was too low to encourage development of compliant
coatings.  Other commenters thought that it was too high
relative to the price of some products or in light of the
additional costs associated with recordkeeping for this
option.  One commenter suggested a phase-in of the fee.  For a
                             6-41

-------
more complete description of the comments on this option, see
Section 2.4.2 of the Architectural Coatings Regulation BID.
     Several factors affected the selection of fee level,
including the benefit per ton of VOC reductions value
historically used in analyses under the Clean Air Act, the
historical range of acceptable cost-effectiveness values for
VOC, the magnitude of the loss in emission reductions, and the
effect on the market model (price and output adjustments,
distribution of welfare impacts across consumers and
producers, and changes in social cost) as well as the effect
of different exceedance fee rates on the industry
cost-to-revenues ratio.
     More specifically, the value chosen for analysis at
proposal is slightly higher than the benefit transfer value
(i.e., the benefit value per ton of VOC reduced)  historically
used in EPA analyses and is also slightly higher than
historical cost-effectiveness values for VOCs.  This was
intended to provide incentive for manufacturers to continue to
strive to find low-cost methods of reducing the VOC content in
their products.  Therefore, manufacturers that find the fee to
be the lowest-cost option of compliance with the regulation
(in comparison to reformulation or losing profits from product
withdrawal)  would pay the fee, but be encouraged to find an
even lower-cost solution to reduce total production costs in
the long run.
     Another consideration was the amount of emission
reductions lost at the selected fee level.  This level also
proved to provide only minor adjustments in market price and
quantity in comparison to reformulation by itself, while
providing substantial flexibility to manufacturers of
small-volume products or products that exceed the standards by
a small amount.  The Agency also evaluated a higher fee rate
prior to proposal and found that social cost increased with a
                             6-42

-------
relatively small change in lost emission reductions (as
compared to the lower fee rate).   The selected fee rate was
thus set high enough to make reformulation attractive for the
majority of producers, but low enough to allow a small sector
of products to remain on the market in lieu of withdrawal.
Also, the lost emission reductions will be limited and the
impact on the markets will be minor.  The Agency also examined
the effect of varying the fee rate on the fee adoption rates,
social cost impacts, foregone emission reduction, and small
business impacts.   This analysis showed that at lower fee
rates (e.g., $l,500/ton and $l,000/ton) there was a
significant increase in the amount of foregone emission
reductions and only a small decrease in the average
cost-to-revenues ratio for small businesses.80
     Based on the economic analysis, the EPA believes that the
fee is set at an appropriate level.  The economic model
compares the cost of paying the fee to the cost of
reformulation for surveyed products.  While many products are
projected to opt for the fee, these products are uniformly
small in volume; thus, their contribution to total market
output  (and emission  reduction)  is relatively small.  It
generally would not be advantageous for producers of
large-volume products, which generate a disproportionately
large share of emissions, to opt for the fee over
reformulation.  Furthermore, the existence of the fee provides
continued incentive for fee-paying firms to reduce VOC
contents on the margin, because this will reduce the amount of
fee they must pay.
     Some commenters suggested that the EPA should base the
fee on price, rather than the quantity of VOC emitted by the
product.  The premise is that only a large proportional price
effect will induce large changes in behavior.  The objective
of a pollution fee, however, is to "charge" for the pollution
                             6-43

-------
generated.  The only consistent way to accomplish this is to
have the fee payment depend on the amount of pollution
generated.  It is not clear how a price-based fee would be
tied to the amount of VOC emitted.  For instance, a low-priced
high-VOC product could have a fee per unit that is much lower
than a high-priced lower-VOC product.  In this case, the fee
mechanism would not work to ensure enough incentive for the
higher-VOC product to reduce VOC content.  In other words, a
ton of extra emissions from one product would incur less of a
fee than a ton of extra emissions from the other.  For
example, such a mechanism would favor very high-VOC content
products that are very inexpensive.  Alternatively, having one
ton of exceeded emissions face the same fee, regardless of
source is more efficient, and seemingly more fair.
     The combination of the compliance options in the final
rule provides the phase-in of the fee suggested by some
commenters.  Specifically, the phasing of the tonnage
exemption in combination with the exceedance fee provision
will operate to increase the fee for products that exceed the
VOC content limits in the rule.  In the time period from the
compliance deadline through the year 2000, manufacturers may
exempt from regulation 25 tons (23 Mg) of VOC, so total fee
payments would be lower than in the second year.  The
following year, 2001, has a lower exemption level of 12 tons
(11 Mg) of VOC, so fee payments would be slightly greater for
those manufacturers who choose not to reformulate or otherwise
reduce the VOC content of their products.  In the next year
and any subsequent year of compliance, the fee rate would
become level because the exemption level remains the same at
5 tons  (4.5 Mg) per year.  The fee payments would also provide
incentive for manufacturers to find lower-cost VOC technology
to meet the standard and eliminate or reduce their fee
payments.
                             6-44

-------
6.3.4  Extended Compliance Time for Small Businesses
     At proposal the Agency requested comment on whether the
final rule should include a compliance extension for small
businesses.81   In effect, this  extension would have  allowed
small businesses 12 additional months to comply.  Thirteen
commenters commented on the small business compliance
extension concept.  Two-thirds of the commenters providing
comments on this provision were against special treatment for
small businesses.  The primary concern was that this provision
would provide  small businesses an unfair advantage  in the
marketplace.   Some of the commenters opposing the extension
noted that an  extension should not be necessary because of the
specialized coating categories and the VOC content  limits for
these categories, small volume exemption, the potential
exceedance fee compliance option, and the variance  provision.
     After careful evaluation of the comments, the  Agency has
decided not to include a compliance extension specific to
small businesses but has instead lengthened the compliance
period for all regulated entities to 12 months.  This time
period was selected to balance the needs of the regulated
entities, both large and small businesses, against  the need
for rapid implementation of the rule to achieve the required
reductions of VOC emissions.
6.3.5  Compliance Variances
     In the proposal preamble the Agency requested  comments
from small businesses on their expected use of a compliance
variance provision.82  The proposed compliance variance
provision would have allowed manufacturers and importers of
architectural coatings to submit a written application to the
Administrator requesting a variance if,  for reasons beyond
their reasonable control,  they could not comply with the
requirements of the proposed rule.   In particular,  the
proposed variance provision allowed additional compliance time
                             6-45

-------
and was developed especially for small businesses,  but would
have been available to any size business.
     Of the 22 commenters on this provision,  only
eight commenters supported the concept.  The 14 commenters
opposing the concept included some small businesses.  Concerns
expressed by those commenters included concerns that it would
impose such a heavy burden that businesses would choose to
shut down rather than use the variance and that the variance
requirements as proposed are unduly difficult to achieve.  For
example, one commenter noted that the variance provision as
proposed required significant expense with little or no
guarantee of approval.  The commenter recommended an extended
compliance period as a more effective option to alleviate the
heavy burden upon small businesses.
     Based on the comments received,  the Agency concluded that
the variance provision may not provide the intended additional
compliance flexibility, especially for small businesses.
Therefore, the variance provision has not been included in the
final rule.  Even though the proposed variance requirements
were intended to be the minimum necessary to approve a coating
variance, the requirements may have been burdensome,
particularly for small businesses with limited or no
regulatory compliance staff.  It is also possible that the
variance provision could create an uneven playing field
because small businesses would not have the resources needed
to pursue this option, thereby putting small businesses at a
disadvantage compared to large businesses.  Also, as one
commenter pointed out, even with the investment of time and
money, the Agency cannot guarantee approval of the variance
application.  In addition, review and approval of numerous
variance applications would place a heavy burden on EPA's
staff, thereby delaying implementation of the intended
flexibility to the disadvantage of regulated entities.
                             6-46

-------
     Nevertheless, there is still value in providing
additional compliance flexibility; therefore, new provisions
have been incorporated into the final rule (i.e., the tonnage
exemption that phases down over time and the exceedance fee
option).   These provisions provide even greater flexibility
than the variance provision and are less burdensome.  Both of
these compliance options are automatically available to all
regulated entities and, thus, do not involve complex
application and approval processes.  However, these compliance
options do require some minimal recordkeeping and reporting.
     The tonnage exemption will allow each regulated entity to
exempt from the VOC content limit anywhere from 7,000 to
30,000 gallons of coatings the first 15 months; 3,400 to
14,400 gallons the second year; and 1,400 to 6,000 gallons the
third year and beyond  (the actual amount exempted depends on
the VOC content of the product(s)).  Therefore, this exemption
is ideal for low-volume products that cannot be reformulated
in the foreseeable future.
     The exceedance fee option is designed to give
manufacturers additional time to develop lower-VOC
technologies, if necessary.  This option allows regulated
entities to continue to sell coatings that exceed the VOC
content limits in addition to the coatings for which they are
claiming the low-volume exemption, provided they pay an
exceedance fee.  The amount of the fee is based on the volume
of the product sold, the VOC content of the product, the VOC
content applicable to the product, and the fee rate.
     In addition to these provisions, the compliance time,
which concerned some commenters, has been extended to
12 months, and the EPA added seven new specialty coatings
categories (e.g., zone markings, concrete curing and sealing,
conversion varnishes)  to the final rule and increased the VOC
content limits for four coating categories.
                             6-47

-------
6.3.6  Selection of Recordkeeping and Reporting Requirements
     The EPA also selected the recordkeeping and reporting
requirements of the rule,  taking into consideration the
impacts of the rule on small businesses.  The EPA designed the
proposed rule to require only those recordkeeping and
reporting requirements necessary to allow determination of
compliance and enforcement,  if necessary.  The proposed rule
required an initial report and labeling of containers for
manufacturers who choose to demonstrate compliance by meeting
the VOC content limits in the standard.  There were no
additional reports or records required from these
manufacturers.  Additional recordkeeping and reporting
requirements were proposed for the recycled coatings option,
the exceedance fee option, and the low-volume exemption
option.
     Two industry commenters requested even more limited
recordkeeping and reporting requirements in the rule and
several industry commenters noted the need to correct dates
and clarify some of the labeling requirements in the proposed
rule.  In the final rule,  the EPA has maintained the proposed
recordkeeping and reporting requirements for manufacturers who
choose to demonstrate compliance by meeting the VOC content
limit in the standard.  The EPA has also clarified the
container labeling requirements and provided additional
flexibility for labeling of VOC content of the coating as well
as for placement of the date codes.  In the final rule, the
EPA required only those records and information necessary to
determine compliance with the compliance alternatives of the
exceedance fee, the tonnage exemption,  and the credit for
recycling of coatings.  Specifically, the final rule only
requires semiannual reporting from manufacturers who elect to
use the exceedance fee compliance option and annual reporting
from manufacturers who elect to use the tonnage exemption or
                             6-48

-------
the recycled coatings provision.  These records and reports
are essential for enforcing these provisions and the EPA
believes that these records and reports do not represent an
undue burden on manufacturers or importers who elect to use
these optional compliance provisions.  For example, as noted
earlier, the estimated cost for reporting and recordkeeping of
the exceedance fee provision at a company with an average of
eight reformulations would be approximately 0.1 percent of
sales revenue, which is not a significant burden.

6.4  SMALL BUSINESS IMPACT SUMMARY

     The potential for significant impacts on small businesses
of the regulation arise from two primary sources:

     •   Products  made  by  small  producers,  on  average,  have  a
        higher VOC  content  than the  industry  average.

     •   The  costs of reformulating products to  comply  with  the
        regulation  are  independent of product volume and
        thereby impose  higher average costs per  unit of product
        on small  volume coatings.

     The first problem is related to small producers'  tendency
to specialize in coatings categories that are naturally higher
in VOC content and to their tendency to concentrate in the
"high-VOC" end of the distribution of products within a given
category.  Thus  the potential for disproportionate impacts of
VOC reduction regulation on small businesses  follows partly
from the fact that  small businesses  contribute a
disproportionate  amount of the  aggregate VOC  emissions that
are targeted for  reduction.
     The second  problem follows from the nature of
reformulation costs.   A coating's formula is  the product  of an
intellectual capital  investment, much like the development of
                             6-49

-------
a drug or a computer software product.   The cost of the
investment follows directly from the level of effort necessary
to revise the formula to meet both the VOC standards imposed
by the regulation and performance standards imposed by the
marketplace.   This level of effort is essentially independent
of the quantity of the product that is eventually sold.
Therefore, the relative impacts on smaller volume products is,
by definition, greater.
     The data used in this analysis suggest that these two
primary factors are relevant in the case of small
architectural coatings producers.  The average VOC content of
the products made by the small business producers in the
survey is 75 percent higher than the average VOC content of
all products combined.  A little over half of the difference
in the averages is attributed to the specialization of small
producers in high-VOC content product categories, with the
remainder attributed to the tendency for small businesses to
produce higher VOC products within each product group.
Moreover, the average product volume of products made by small
businesses is less than 20 percent of the average product
volume for the entire survey population, implying much larger
average reformulation costs.  Thus, without mitigating
factors, the impacts on small businesses are potentially
significant.
     The regulation has been designed to mitigate small
business impacts.  Despite their inherently higher VOC
content, the proportion of small business products exceeding
the regulatory standards is not much higher than the
corresponding proportion for the survey population at large
(42 percent vs. 36 percent).  In addition, the availability of
the exceedance fee option is beneficial to small business
producers because it places an upper bound on the per-unit
costs of compliance.  Data analyzed in this study indicate
                             6-50

-------
that small business producer costs are reduced by nearly
one-quarter when the exceedance fee is introduced and the
possibility of product withdrawal is considered in lieu of
reformulation.  The cost/revenue ratio exemplifies the
advantages of the lower-cost compliance options (the fee and
withdrawal) in that the ratio for small businesses drops from
2.5 percent to 2.0 percent.
     In addition to adding the exceedance fee and the tonnage
exemption to the final rule, the EPA also increased the
compliance time to 12 months and added seven new product
categories and increased the VOC content limits for four
categories.  These changes were made in response to public
comments to further mitigate the rule's small business
impacts.  The analysis of the impacts of the final rule shows
that these provisions are likely to be used by small entities
and the impact on a typical small firm is reduced without
significant reduction in the emission reductions achieved by
the rule.  The EPA believes that these measures adopted in the
final rule represent a significant mitigation of the economic
impacts on small businesses compared to the impacts that might
otherwise have occurred.
                             6-51

-------
                           SECTION 7
                           EPILOGUE
     Because regulatory development is an evolving process,
the final Table of Standards for VOC content limits differs
slightly from the interim Table of Standards used in the
analysis reported here.  The main difference between the two
sets of standards (see Table 7-1) is the addition of new
categories in the final standards and the revision of content
limits for other categories.  These two dimensions of change
are evaluated in turn below.

7.1  NEW PRODUCT CATEGORIES

     The final standards added seven product categories not
included in the interim standards.  These are:

     •  calcimine  recoaters
     •  concrete curing and  sealing  compounds
     •  concrete surface retarders
     •  conversion varnish
     •  faux  finish/glazing
     •  stain controllers
     •  zone  marking coatings
                              7-1

-------
  TABLE 7-1.   TABLE OF STANDARDS:   INTERIM VS. FINAL
Architectural Coatings
       Category
     VOC Content Limit
	(g/L)	

    Interim
 (see Table 2-1)    Final
Difference
Antenna coatings
Anti fouling coatings
Antigraffiti coatings
Bituminous coatings and mastics
Bond breakers
Calcimine recoater
Chalkboard resurfacers
Concrete curing compounds
Concrete curing and sealing
compounds
Concrete protective coatings
Concrete surface retarders
Conversion varnish
Dry fog coatings
Extreme high-durability
coatings
Faux finishing/glazing
Fire-retardant /resistive
coatings
Clear
Opaque
Flat coatings, N.O.S.
Exterior
Interior
Floor coatings
Flow coatings
Form release compounds
Graphic arts coatings (sign
paints)
Heat reactive coatings
High- temperature coatings
Impacted immersion coatings
Industrial maintenance coatings
500
450
600
500
600
NA
450
350
NA
400
NA
NA
400
800

NA


850
450

250
250
400
650
450
500
420
650
780
450
530
450
600
500
600
475
450
350
700
400
780
725
400
800

700


850
450

250
250
400
650
450
500
420
650
780
450
Limit increased




New category


New category

New category
New category



New category















                                                        (continued)
                             7-2

-------
TABLE 7-1.   TABLE OF STANDARDS:   INTERIM VS.  FINAL (CONTINUED)
VOC Content Limit
(g/D
Architectural Coatings
Category
Lacquers (including lacquer
sanding sealers)
Magnesite cement coatings
Mastic texture coatings
Metallic pigmented coatings
Multicolor coatings
Nonferrous ornamental metal
lacquers
Nonflat coatings, N.O.S.
Exterior
Interior
Nuclear coatings
Pretreatment wash primers
Primers and undercoaters,
N.O.S.
Quick dry coatings
Enamels
Primers, sealers, and
undercoaters
Repair and maintenance
thermoplastic coatings
Roof coatings
Rust preventive coatings
Sanding sealers
Sealers
Shellacs
Clear
Opaque
Stains
Clear and semi transparent
Opaque
Waterborne low solids
Stain controllers
Interim
(see Table 2-1)
680
600
300
500
580
870

380
380
450
780
350

450
450
650
250
400
550
400

650
550

550
350
120
NA
Final Difference
680
600
300
500
580
870

380
380
450
780
350

450
450
650
250
400
550
400

730 Limit increased
550

550
350
120
720 New category
                                                       (continued)
                              7-3

-------
TABLE 7-1.   TABLE OF STANDARDS:   INTERIM VS. FINAL (CONTINUED)
    Architectural Coatings
          Category
    VOC Content Limit
	(g/L)	
    Interim
 (see Table 2-1)    Final
        Difference
Swimming pool coatings
Thermoplastic rubber coatings
and mastics
Traffic marking paints
Varnishes
Waterproofing sealers and
treatments
       600
       550

       150
       450
600
550

150
450
Clear
Opaque
Wood preservatives
Below ground
Clear and semi transparent
Opaque
Low solids
Zone marking coatings
Total New Categories
Total Limit Changes
600
400

550
550
350
NA
NA
7
4
600
600

550
550
350
120
450



Limit increased





New category


     By and  large,  new categories were  added to accommodate
specialty products  that were previously included in other
categories with  lower (more stringent)  VOC limits.   As a
result, some products that would be over the limit  in the
previous category,  thereby necessitating a compliance action
(reformulate,  fee payment, withdrawal),  are no longer
constrained  by the  regulation.  In these cases, the addition
of the new categories reduces the number of required
compliance actions,  as a result, also cuts compliance costs
and the quantity of emission reductions.
      However, one  of the new product categories,  concrete
curing and sealing  (CCS) compounds, applies to products that
were considered  outside of the  regulated universe in the
economic analysis presented in  this report.  Therefore, the
                               7-4

-------
compliance actions required for those products are not
estimated in this analysis.  The potential cost implications
of that omission are discussed below.
     Supplemental data could be obtained for only two of the
seven new product categories.  These data were gathered after
proposal and are used here to estimate the likely impact of
these new categories on regulatory costs.
     One of the categories for which supplemental data were
obtained is the zone markings category.  First, we note that
46 products from the original survey data in the traffic
paints category have VOC contents that are greater than
150 g/L (the final traffic marking paints content limit) and
450 g/L (the zone markings limit).  These 46 products
constitute the entire list of surveyed products that could
potentially be relieved from compliance by the addition of the
higher zone markings limit.  According to data from the state
of Texas,  zone markings constitute approximately 9 percent of
all traffic coatings.83  We use this percentage to estimate the
number of those 46 products that are zone markings,  yielding
an estimate of 4.1 (decimals are used to reflect an averaging
effect).  Using an expansion factor of 3.0 to reflect the
scale of the national estimate of traffic coatings to the
survey estimate, we estimate that 12.3 products nationwide can
avoid compliance action due to the addition of the new zone
markings category.
     Data were gathered for 77 CCS products with a total
product volume of 11.2 million liters.84  Of these 77 products,
38 were determined to exceed the content limit of 700 g/L.   As
described in Section 2 of this report, the number of
noneompliant coatings is reduced by a factor of one-third to
estimate the total number of noncompliant coatings needing a
compliance action (reformulation, fee, or withdrawal).   After
this adjustment, 25 of the 77  CCS products surveyed are
                              7-5

-------
estimated to require compliance action.  The CCS data also
indicate an estimate of 37.8 million liters of CCS products
nationwide.  Taking the ratio of national CCS volume to the
volume captured in the supplemental data collection
(37.8/11.2) and multiplying by the 25 surveyed products
needing compliance action yields a national estimate of CCS
compliance actions of 85.6 products.
     Taking the 85.6 additional compliance actions due to the
new CCS category together with the 12.3 fewer compliance
actions due to the zone markings category yields a net
increase of 73.3 compliance actions.  To approximate the
social cost implications, we take the ratio of the total
social costs from the architectural coatings market analysis
($20.2 million in Table 3-2) and divide by the total number of
compliance actions in the analysis  (2,345 products in
Table 2-2) to get a social cost per compliance action of
approximately $8,600.  Multiplying this number by
74 compliance actions gives a social cost estimate of
approximately $632,000 ($1991).

7.2  CATEGORIES WITH HIGHER VOC CONTENT LIMITS

     Besides the additional categories, VOC content limits
were higher (less stringent) in the final standards than in
the interim standards for the following categories:

     •  antenna  coatings
     •  shellacs,  clear
     •  waterproofing sealers  and  treatments,  opaque

     The survey data indicate that nine products in these
three product categories would have been noncompliant under
the interim standards but are compliant under the final

                              7-6

-------
standards.  Reducing the nine otherwise noncompliant products
by one-third yields an estimate of six compliance actions
within the survey population that are avoided by the higher
content limit in the final standards.  Because the volume of
surveyed products in these categories roughly equals the
national sales estimates, the estimated number of avoided
compliance actions nationwide is also six.  Multiplying this
number by the social cost estimate of $8,600 yields an
estimate for the reduction of social costs caused by the new
content limits of approximately $52,000.  Subtracting this
from the net cost increase quantified for the new product
categories reduces the cost estimate to about $580,000
($1991) .

7.3  SUMMARY

     The VOC content standards included in the final rule
differ from the limits analyzed in this report. The difference
between the two sets of standards are the inclusion of seven
new product categories and an increase in the content limits
(reduction in stringency) for three product categories.
     Because of data limitations, only a subset of these
changes lend themselves to quantification of potential costs
impacts.  The net quantified effect is a $580,000 increase in
the estimate of annual social costs.  However, this increase
in cost must be considered against the unquantified decrease
in costs from the expected fall in compliance due to the five
other new categories.  Without additional data, it is
difficult to conclude whether the cost reductions from those
categories will together outweigh the net cost increases
quantified.  Given that the social cost effects quantified
here are less than 3 percent of the total estimated social
costs of the regulation, factors that reduce  (or reverse the
                              7-7

-------
sign)  of these costs lead to the conclusion that the total
social cost estimate is not greatly affected by the
differences between the interim standards used in the analysis
and the final standards issued in the rule.
                              7-8

-------
                          REFERENCES
1.    Stigliani, William M.  Chemical Emissions from the
     Processing and Use of Materials:  the Need for an
     Integrated Emissions Accounting System.  Ecological
     Economics 2^(4) :325-341.   1990.  (Adapted from Figure 2).

2.    Industry Insights.  Architectural and Industrial
     Maintenance Surface Coatings VOC Emissions Inventory
     Survey.  Prepared for the National Paint and Coatings
     Association in cooperation with the AIM Regulatory
     Negotiation Industry Caucus.  Final Draft Report.  1993.

3.    U.S. Department of Commerce.  1987 Census of
     Manufactures, Industry Series:  Paints and Allied
     Products.  Washington, DC, Government Printing Office.
     1990.

4.    Ref. 2.

5.    Ref. 2.

6.    National Paint and Coatings Association.  U.S. Paint
     Industry Data Base.  Menlo Park, CA, SRI International.
     1992.

7.    Whittington, Trevellyan V.  Paint Fundamentals. In Paint
     Handbook, Guy E. Weismantel (ed.).  New York, McGraw-
     Hill.  Pp. 1-1 to 1-23.   1981.

8.    Beno, J., W. Brown, and P.P. Obst.  Formulating and Using
     Water Based Thermoplastic Resins for Wood Finishing.  In
     Proceedings of the Nineteenth Water-Borne, Higher-Solids,
     and Powder Coatings Symposium.  Robson F. Storey and
     Shelby F. Thames  (eds.).  University of Southern
     Mississippi, Department of Polymer Science.  Pp. 626-638.
     1992.

9.    Singer, Elias.  Raw Materials.  In Paint Handbook, Guy E.
     Weismantel  (ed.).  New York, McGraw-Hill.  Pp. 3-1 to
     3-22. 1981.

                              R-l

-------
10.  Rauch Associates, Inc.  The Rauch Guide to the U.S. Paint
     Industry.  Bridgewater, NJ, Rauch Associates, Inc.  1990.

11.  Ref. 9.

12.  Kemezis, Paul.  Wait-and-See Stance Taken on Zero-VOC
     Architectural Paints.  Chemical Week.  Pp. 52-53.
     October 1992.

13.  Ref. 8.

14.  Ref. 10.

15.  Ref. 7.

16.  Ref. 7.  (Adapted from Figure 1.4).

17.  Ref. 10.

18.  Bakke, Timothy 0.  Clean Air Paints.  Popular Science.
     23J7:85.  August 1990.

19.  D'Amico, Esther.  Waterborne Systems Gaining Niche By
     Niche.  Chemical Marketing Reporter.  238(18);SR20-SR28.
     1990.

20.  Ref. 18.

21.  Ref. 18.

22.  Ref. 18.

23.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial Reports:
     Paints and Allied Products, 1982.  Washington,  DC,
     Government Printing Office.  1983.

24.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial Reports:
     Paints and Allied Products, 1983.  Washington,  DC,
     Government Printing Office.  1984.

25.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial Reports:
     Paints and Allied Products, 1984.  Washington,  DC,
     Government Printing Office.  1985.

26.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial Reports:
     Paints and Allied Products, 1985.  Washington,  DC,
     Government Printing Office.  1986.

27.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial Reports:
     Paints and Allied Products, 1986.  Washington,  DC,
     Government Printing Office.  1987.

                              R-2

-------
28.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial Reports:
     Paints and Allied Products, 1987.  Washington, DC,
     Government Printing Office.  1988.

29.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial Reports:
     Paints and Allied Products, 1988.  Washington, DC,
     Government Printing Office.  1989.

30.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial Reports:
     Paints and Allied Products, 1989.  Washington, DC,
     Government Printing Office.  1990.

31.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial Reports:
     Paints and Allied Products, 1990.  Washington, DC,
     Government Printing Office.  1991.

32.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial Reports:
     Paints and Allied Products, 1991.  Washington, DC,
     Government Printing Office.  1992.

33.  O'Reilly, Richard.  Product Development Drives Market
     Growth.  In:  Standard and Poor's Industry Surveys:
     Chemicals Current Analysis.  Pp. C40-C43.  New York,
     Standard and Poor's Corporation.  1991.

34.  Ref. 33.

35.  Ref. 33.

36.  Johnson, Duane.  The Best Paint for the Job.  Family
     Handyman. 42^:18.  June 1992.

37.  Consumer Reports Magazine.  Interior Latex Paints,
     p. 333.  May 1991.

38.  National Paint Coatings Association.  The Household Paint
     Selector.  New York, Barnes and Noble Books.  1975.

39.  Ref. 3.

40.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  The 1982 Benchmark Input-
     Output Accounts of the United States.  Washington, DC,
     Government Printing Office.  1991.

41.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  Census of Manufactures,
     Subject Series:  Type of Organization.  Washington, DC,
     Government Printing Office, February 1991.
                              R-3

-------
42.  Source for Percentage Accounted for Data:  U.S.
     Department of Commerce.  1987 Census of Manufactures,
     Concentration Ratios of Manufacturers.  Washington, DC,
     Government Printing Office.  1992.

43.  Telecon.  Lindsay, Sam.  Small Business Administration,
     with Dempsey, Jenny.  Research Triangle Institute,
     July 6, 1993.

44.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  1987 Economic Censuses.
     Volume 1, Report Series, Release ID.  Census of
     Manufactures:  Location of Manufacturing Plants.  file
     MC87LMCO.  1991.

45.  Ref. 10.

46.  Ref. 3.

47.  Loesel, Andrew.  Coatings Industry Faces New Mix.  In
     Chemical Marketing Reporter.  238(18);SR3-SR8.  1990.

48.  Ref. 47.

49.  Finishers' Management.  The U.S. Paint and Coatings
     Industry.  Pp. 23-25.  April 1991.

50.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  U.S. Industrial Outlook
     '92, Business Forecasts for 350 Industries.  Washington,
     DC, Government Printing Office.  1992.

51.  AIM Coatings Regulatory Negotiation Committee meeting.
     July 28-30, 1993, Washington, DC.  Meeting Summary.

52.  Ref. 51.

53.  Office of Management and Budget.  Guidelines and Discount
     Rates for Benefit-Cost Analysis of Federal Programs.
     Memorandum for Heads of Executive Departments and
     Establishments.  Circular No. A-94 Revised (Transmittal
     Memo No. 64).  October 29, 1992.

54.  ICF Consulting Associates, Incorporated.  Small Business
     Economic Impact Study.  Prepared for the South Coast Air
     Quality Management District.  Final Report.  June 17,
     1988.

55.  Ref. 2.

56.  Ref. 2.
                              R-4

-------
57.   Telecon between Chris Sarsony,  Eastern Research Group to
     Brian Murray, Research Triangle Institute, December 15
     1997.

58.   U.S. Department of Commerce.  1991 Annual Survey of
     Manufactures: Statistics for Industry Groups and
     Industries.  Washington, DC, Government Printing Office.
     1992.

59.   Ref. 2.

60.   Memorandum.  Seagroves, Monica, Eastern Research Group,
     to Ducey, Ellen, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency.
     January 7, 1998.  Architectural coatings certification
     and registration information from Massachusetts
     Department of Environmental Protection.

61.   Ref. 58.

62.   Ref. 58.

63.   Ref. 58.

64.   Eastern Research Group.  "Traffic Coating Analysis.*
     Prepared for the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency,
     Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards.
     Morrisville, NC:  Eastern Research Group.  1998.

65.   Ref. 64.

66.   Eastern Research Group.  "Emission Reduction from the
     Final Architectural Coatings VOC Rule.*  Prepared for the
     U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Office of Air
     Quality Planning and Standards.  Morrisville, NC:
     Eastern Research Group.  1998.

67.   Ref. 3.

68.   Ref. 2.

69.   Ref. 2.

70.   Ref. 2.

71.   Ref. 2.

72.   Memorandum.  Nelson, Robert, National Paint & Coatings
     Association, to Madariaga,  Bruce, EPA/OAQPS.   October 14,
     1993.
                              R-5

-------
73.  Ref. 51.

74.  Ref. 2.

75.  Ref. 2.

76.  61 FR 32740.

77.  61 FR 32741.

78.  Ref. 77.

79.  Ref. 76.

80.  Memorandum from Murray,  Brian,  Research Triangle
     Institute, to Evans,  Ron,  Environmental Protection
     Agency.  July 1, 1998.   AIM SBREFA analysis.

81.  61 FR 32732.

82.  61 FR 32743.

83.  Telecon.  Seagroves,  Monica,  Eastern Research Group, with
     Turner, Mel, Standard Paints.  April 22, 1997.  Comment
     clarification—zone category.

84.  Facsimile.  Sarsony,  Chris,  Eastern Research Group, with
     Murray, Brian, Research Triangle Institute.  June 29,
     1998.  Calculation sheet:   concrete curing and sealing
     compounds.
                              R-6

-------
         APPENDIX A

    MARKET DEFINITION,
DEMAND ESTIMATION, AND DATA

-------
A.I  PRODUCT/MARKET CROSS-REFERENCE METHOD
     Data on coating prices, quantities, average VOC contents,
and VOC content limits are necessary to estimate the effect of
VOC content limits on architectural coatings products.  Price
and quantity data were taken from the 1991 Current Industrial
Reports:  Paint and Allied Products.1  The Architectural and
Industrial Maintenance Surface Coatings Survey  (the survey)2
provided the sales-weighted average VOC emissions, which
represent VOC content.  VOC content limits were from the TOS
developed by EPA.
     Census data are organized according to product codes,
which define product categories; however, these Census product
categories differ from the product categories in the survey.
Furthermore, the TOS  (see Table 2-1) gives VOC content limits
for product categories that differ slightly from those
categories for which data are provided in the survey.  Data
from all three sources are necessary to conduct the economic
impact analysis.  Therefore, a fourth product categorization
was constructed, which is called market segments,  that
aggregates the categories so that data may be used from all
three sources to provide the necessary level of resolution for
market analysis.  Table A-l illustrates the individual product
categories represented by each data source and how they map
into the market segments used in the analysis.3'4
     The mapping in Table A-l proceeds from the most
aggregated category to the least aggregated category.  In some
cases,  however, the survey provides more detail than the TOS.
                              A-l

-------
                       TABLE  A-l.   PRODUCT/MARKET CROSS-REFERENCE


Market Segment
Exterior solventborne











Exterior waterborne











Interior solventborne





Interior waterborne



Solventborne primers
and undercoaters
group




Current Industrial Report Census Category
Exterior solvent paints and tinting
bases, including barn and roof paints
Exterior solvent enamels and tint.
including ex. -in floor enamels
Other exterior solvent coatings.
including bituminous paints






Exterior water pelnts end tinting bases.
including barn and roof paints
Exterior water exterior- -interior deck
end floor enamels

Other exterior water coatings






Interior flat solvent wall paints and
tinting bases
Interior solvent gloss and quick dry
enamels and other solvent paints and tint
Interior semigloss. eggshell, satin solvent
paints and tinting bases
Interior flat water paints and tinting
bases
Interior semigloss, eggshell, aatln and
other water paints and tints
Exterior solvent undercoaters and primers
Interior solvent undercoaters and primers



Census
Product
Code
2851112

2851115

2851139







2851141

2851142


2851155






2851163

2851165

2851169

2851181

2851183

2851125
2851171




VOC Emission Inventory
Survey Category
Roof coatings- -
solventborne
Flat, exterior.
solventborne
High performance arch.
coatings- -solvent
Bituminous coatings--
solvent


Nonflat, exterior--
solvent
Plat, exterior.
water borne
Roof coatings--
water borne
Nonflat, exterior--
waterborne
High performance arch.
coatings- -water
Bituminous coatings--
water


Plat, tnterlor--
solventborne
Nonflat, interior--
solventborne
Quick dry enamels

Plat, interior--
waterborne
Nonflat, interior--
water borne
Primers, solventborne
Undercoaters,
solventborne
Q.D. primers, sealers,
undercoaters - - sol vent

Table of Standards Proposed
Regulation Limits Category
Roof coatings*

Flat, exterior*

High performance, floor coatings*

Bituminous coatings and mastics*
High performance, rust preventive*
High performance, concrete
protective*
Nonflat, exterior*

Flat, exterior*

Roof coatings*

Nontlat, exterior*

High performance, floor coetings*

Bituminous coatings and mastics*
High performance, rust preventive*
High performance, concrete
protective*
Plat, interior.*

Nonflat, interior*

Quick dry enamels

Flet, interior*

Nonflat, interior*

Primers and undercoaters*


Quick dry primers, sealers.
undercoaters*
See notes at end of table.
(continued)

-------
                            TABLE  A-l.    PRODUCT/MARKET  CROSS-REFERENCE  (CONTINUED)
     Market Safltsant
                             Currant Industrial Report Census Category
                                                   Census
                                                  Product
                                                    Code
             VOC Emlnion Inventory
                 Survey Category
 Table of Standard! Proposed
 Regulation Limits Category
 Waterborne primera
     and undercoatera
     group
Exterior water undercoetera and primers
Interior water undercoatera and prlaiara
2851144   Priatara, waterborne
2851186   Undercoaters,  waterborne
          Q.D. primers,  sealers,
              undercoaters--water
Primera and undercoaters*

Quick dry primers, sealers,
    undercoatera*
 Solventborne clear
     coating, aealer,
     and atain
Exterior aolvent clear finishes and aeelera         28511J5
Interior aolvent clear finishes and aealers         2851175
Exterior aolvent stains                            1851137
Interior aolvent atains                            1851177
          Sealers, solventborne
          Shellacs
                                                                                     Waterproofing  sealers
                                                                                         w/pigment, solvent
                                                                                     Waterproofing  sealers--
                                                                                         clear,  solvent
                                                                                     Varnishes,  solventborne
                                                                                     Stains,  opaque,  solventborne
                                                                                     Stains,  semitransparent,
                                                                                         solventborn*
Seal era*
Sealera--shellacs, clear
Sealera--shellacs, opaque

Waterproofing  aeelers.
    opaque*
Materproofing  sealers, clear*

Varnishes*
Staina,  opaque*
Stains,  clear  and
    semi transparent*
 Waterborne clear
     coatings and
     stains group
Exterior water  atains and sealers
                         Other interior water coatinga,  ataina,  and
                             aealers
                                                  2851149    Staina,  opaque,  waterborne
                                                            Sealers,  waterborne
                                                            Staina,  semi transparent,
                                                                waterborne
                                                  2851188    Waterproofing sealers
                                                                w/pigment. water
                                                            Waterproofing sealera--
                                                                clear, water
                                                            Varnishes,  waterborne
                                         Staina, opaque*
                                         Sealers'
                                         Staina, clear, and
                                             seaU t ranaparent*
                                         Waterproofing aaalers,
                                             opaque*
                                         Waterproofing aealera,  clear*

                                         Varnishes*
                                         Staina, low solids
 Lacquers
                         Architectural lacquers
                                                                           2851193
                                                                                     Lacquers
                                                                                                                   Lacquers
 Wood preservatives
     group
Other miscellaneous allied paint producta,
    including brush cleanera, nonpreaaur* wood
    preservatives, putty, and glazing compounds,
    etc.
2851598   Wood preservatives,  below-
              ground
          Clear wood preservatives
          feed transplant wood
              preservatives
          Wood preservatives,  opaque
Wood preservetives, below-
    ground
Wood preservetives, cleer,
and semitransparent

Wood preservetives, opaque
 Traffic marking
	painta
Traffic marking painta
                                                  2851311    Traffic paints
                                        Traffic narking painta
 See notes  at  end  of  table.
                                                                                                                                 (continued)

-------
                           TABLE  A-l.    PRODUCT/MARKET  CROSS-REFERENCE   (CONTINUED)
     Market Segment
                            Current Industrie!  Report Census Cat•gory
                                                                           Census
                                                                           Product
                                                                            Cod*
             VOC Emission Inventory
                 Survey Category
 Table of Standard*  Proposed
 Regulation Limits Category
 Special purpose group    Special purpose coatings,  n.s.k.
2851300   Dry fog coatings
          Metallic pigmented coatings

          Antigraffiti coatings
                                                                                     Concrete curino compound*
                                                                                     ratm release compounds
                                                                                     Graphic arts coatings

                                                                                     Multicolor coatings
                                                                                     Pretreatmant wash primers
                                                                                     Swimming pool coatings
Dry fog coating*
Metallic pigmented coatings
Antifouling coatings
Antigraffiti coating*
Bond breekers
Chalkboard resurfacers
Concrete curing compounds
Form release compounds
Graphic arts coating*
Impacted imerslon coating*
Multicolor coating*
Pretreatment waah primers
Swinming pool coating*
Flow coatings
Industrial
Maintenance
group
Interior industrial new construction and
Maintenance paints
Exterior industrial new construction and
maintenance paint*
2851301
2851305
Antenna coating*
Extreme high durability
coatings
                                                                                     Fire-retardant/resistive
                                                                                      coatings
                                                                                     High temperature coatings
                                                                                     Magnesite cement coatings
                                                                                     Mastic  texture coatings
                                                                                     Sanding  sealer*
                                                                                     Industrial maintenance
                                                                                       coating*
                                                                                     Appurtenance*	
                                        Fir*-ret*rdant/re*i*tive
                                          coatings
                                        High temperature coating*
                                        Hagnesit* cement coating*
                                        Mastic texture coating*
                                        Nonferrous ornamental metal
                                          lacquer and surface
                                          protectants
                                        Nuclear power plant coatings
                                        Repair and maintenance
                                          thermoplastic
                                        Sanding sealer*
                                        Thermoplastic rubber coating*
                                          and mastics
                                        Industrial maintenance
                                          coatings
                                        Heat reactive coating*	
• In the TOS,  only one limit for both solvent and waterborne* 1* givani  (or presentation the product 1* listed under both.

Source*;  U.S. Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial  Report*:  Paint and Allied Product*, 1991.  Washington,  D.C. Government Printing Office.
         1993.
         Industry Insights.  Architectural and Industrial  Maintenance Surface Coating* VOC  Emission* Inventory Survey.   Prepared for the National
         Paint and Coating* Association in cooperation with  the AIM Regulatory Negotiation  Industry Caucus.  Final draft  report.  1993.

-------
Where possible, the market segments were paired as solvent
borne and waterborne coating categories.  Separate market
segments could not be created for flat and nonflat coatings in
the interior and exterior segments because the Census data do
not differentiate between exterior flats and nonflats.
     The necessary data were developed for each of the
13 market segments using the mapping scheme presented in
Table A-l.  Data for individual Census product codes were
summed where necessary to compute prices and quantities.

A.2  ESTIMATING DEMAND ELASTICITIES FOR COATINGS

     To perform the market analysis, own- and cross-price
elasticities of demand were estimated for four broad coating
categories:  exterior solventborne and interior solventborne
and their two respective substitutes, exterior waterborne and
interior waterborne.  The variables used in estimation are
domestic consumption quantity; real value of domestic
consumption; real consumption price; national income; a
housing variable; and the real price of alkyd resins, acrylic
resins, and titanium dioxide.  Complete data for these
variables were collected for the years 1981 through 1991.
Justification of these variables and their data sources is
given below.
A.2.1     Estimation Procedure and Results
     Econometric estimation of the interrelated demand system
for interior solventborne,  interior waterborne,  exterior
solventborne, and exterior waterborne architectural coatings
generated estimates of own-price demand elasticities for each
of the four groups and cross-price demand elasticities  between
the solventborne and waterborne segments of each interior
(exterior) pair.
                              A-5

-------
     The quantity demanded  of  a  commodity is a function of its
price,  the price of any substitutes and other factors, such as
income, that affect aggregate  demand.  Estimating the demand
function, however, is more  complicated than just running
regressions of observed market quantities on observed market
prices  and other demand variables.  One must account for the
fact that the observed prices  and quantities are equilibrium
values, which are simultaneously determined by both demand and
supply  factors.
     Variables that are determined within a system  (such as
prices  and quantities in  a  market equilibrium system) are
endogenous to that system,  whereas those variables determined
outside of the particular system (e.g., income, housing
activity) are termed exogenous.  In simultaneous equations
models, endogenous variables are correlated with the error
terms through solution of the  system.  As a result of the
interdependence of the endogenous variables and the error
terms,  the application of standard regression techniques is
modified to estimate the  effect  of an endogenous right-hand
side variable (i.e., equilibrium price) on the endogenous
left-hand dependent variable  (equilibrium quantity).  In
general, ordinary least squares  estimation of the individual
demand  equations leads to biased and inconsistent parameter
estimates when a regressor  is  endogenous.
     Endogeneity bias is  corrected by applying the two-stage
least squares (2SLS) regression  procedure for each estimated
equation  (see, for example, Pindyck and Rubinfield5) .   In the
first stage of the 2SLS method,  the price observations were
regressed against all exogenous  demand and supply variables in
the system.  This regression produced fitted (predicted)
values  for the price variables that are, by definition, highly
correlated with the true  endogenous variable (the observed
                              A-6

-------
equilibrium price) and uncorrelated with  the  error term.  In
the second stage,  these  fitted values were  employed as
observations of  the right-hand side price variables in the
demand equations.  This  procedure  can also  be used to estimate
the underlying structural supply equations; however, because
of the poor performance  of various specifications in the
supply estimations, only demand estimates are reported here.
     The 2SLS procedure  was used to estimate  the four demand
functions.  Both linear  and double-log regressions were
estimated.  The  double-log specifications are presented here
because of slightly better statistical fit  and because the
parameter estimates are  directly interpretable as point
elasticities.
     For the two exterior categories, housing completions are
included as an exogenous demand determinant.  Exogenous supply
factors incorporated into the first-stage regressions include
the prices of various raw material inputs and a price index
for substitute outputs,  which captures the  effect of non-
exterior coatings  prices on the supply of exterior coatings.
For the two interior categories, U.S. domestic GNP is included
as a proxy for the exogenous effect of aggregate income on the
demand for interior coatings.  Exogenous  supply factors
incorporated into  the first-stage  regressions also include the
prices of various  raw material inputs and a price index for
substitute outputs, which in this  case captures the effect of
noninterior coatings prices on the supply of  interior
coatings.  The results of the demand estimations are shown in
Table A-2.
     Unfortunately, sufficient data to estimate the demand
parameters for the other market segments were unavailable.
For the other two  solvent/water-paired segments—clear coatings
and primers/undercoaters—the mean  of the respective own- and
                              A-7

-------
                TABLE A-2.    DEMAND CURVE ESTIMATES
                         Adjustable             Elasticity
	Variable	F£	F-Value    Estimate    t-statistic

 Exterior solventborne      0.94        50.52
 demand

    Log-housing                                     0.17         3.30
    completions

    Log exterior                                    -1.43        -1.89
    solventborne  price

    Log exterior                                     0.20         0.36
    waterborne price

 Exterior waterborne        0.92        39.36
 demand

    Log-housing                                    -0.05        -0.62
    completions

    Log exterior                                     0.51         0.42
    solventborne  price

    Log exterior                                    -1.89        -2.17
    waterborne price

 Interior solventborne      0.69         8.49
 demand
Log GNP
Log interior
solventborne price
Log interior
waterborne price
Interior waterborne 0.99 588.90
demand
Log GNP
Log interior
solventborne price
Log interior
waterborne price
1.01
-1.50
1.43

1.00
0.36
-1.39
1.67
-1.74
1.28

5.07
1.28
-3.80
                                 A-8

-------
cross-price elasticities from the interior and exterior
estimation process were used as proxies for the elasticities.
The other  five segments—special purpose, industrial
maintenance group,  traffic marking paints, lacquers, and wood
preservatives—are specialty groups whose demand is assumed to
be fairly  inelastic and not dependent on prices in the other
segments.    Therefore,  a value of -0.5 for the own-price
demand  elasticity and zero for all cross-price elasticities
were assigned to each of these categories.  Table A-3 provides
the matrix of own- and cross-price elasticities for all
13 market  segments.
A.2.2      Data Used in Demand Estimation
     Domestic consumption quantities and values were
calculated using data from U.S.  Department of Commerce
publications Current Industrial  Reports:  Paint and Allied
Products6'7-8'9-10-11-12-13-14 and U.S. Exports Schedule B Commodity by
Country.15-16-17'18'19-20-21-22   Domestic quantity and value of
shipments  figures were used,  which include exports.  Exports
were then  subtracted to estimate domestic consumption
(architectural coatings imports  are negligible and are not
included in the consumption variable).   Consumer price indexes
from the U.S.  Department of Labor's Handbook of Labor
Statistics23 and the U.S. Department of Commerce's Survey of
Current Business24-25-26 are used to adjust the  current  figures
to real values.   Real  consumption price was imputed for each
product by dividing  real value of domestic consumption by the
quantity of domestic consumption.
                              A-9

-------
         TABLE A-3.  DEMAND ELASTICITY MATRIX FOR ARCHITECTURAL COATINGS MARKET SEGMENTS
I
M
O
Percentage
Change in
Quantity Demand
of Product
Market aegnent
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13





With Respect to
1
-1.43
0.51
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
2
0.20
-1.89
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
3
0
0
-1.50
0.36
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
4
0
0
1.43
-1.39
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
5
0
0
0
0
-1.47
0.44
0
0
0
0
0
0
0




Percentage Change in Price of
6
0
0
0
0
0.82
-1.64
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
7
0
0
0
0
0
0
-1.47
0.44
0
0
0
0
0
8
0
0
0
0
0
0
0.82
-1.64
0
0
0
0
0
9
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
-0.50
0
0
0
0




Product
10
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
-0.50
0
0
0
11
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
-0.50
0
0
12
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
60
-0.50
0
13
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
-0.50

-------
     The GNP  in constant 1987 dollars from  1981  through  1991
was used as an aggregate income measure.*'27-28'29   Housing
completions for 1981  through 1991 were obtained  from  the U.S.
Department of Commerce's Current Construction Reports.30
Prices  for alkyd  and  acrylic resins are obtained from the U.S.
International Trade Commission publication  Synthetic  Organic
Chemicals, U.S. Production and sales .31'32'33'34'35-3S'37'39'39'40  Prices
for titanium  dioxide  were imputed using quantity and  value of
shipment data for U.S.  production from the  Current Industrial
Reports, Inorganic Chemicals.41  Real prices for  these raw
materials were calculated by deflating normal values  using
CPIs.   Alkyd  and  acrylic resins were used to represent raw
materials for the nonvolatile vehicle portion of the  coatings,
which are found mainly in solventborne and  waterborne
coatings, respectively.   Titanium dioxide was used to
represent a raw material in the pigment portion  of the
coating, which is found in both types of coatings.  A
Laspeyres price index was constructed to incorporate  the price
of substitute outputs as a supply-side effect in the  first
stage regressions of  the 2SLS procedure.  Let the price  and
quantity of commodity n in period t be pnc  and  q^,
respectively  for  n -  1,  . ..,  N and t = 0, 1, ...,T.   Then the
Laspeyres price index of the N commodities  for period t
(relative to  the  base period 0)  is defined  as
             N
        *L'E
            N=l
 N
£
N=l
                             0  0
     •All constant values were converted to 1982-1984 dollars for the
analysis to be consistent with the consumer price index (CPI), which has
1982-1984 as a base.
                              A-ll

-------
     Real domestic prices and quantities of nonexterior
coatings were used to construct the price index for the
exterior coatings equations and real domestic prices, and
quantities of noninterior coatings were used to construct the
index for the interior coatings equations.  Each index is
computed for the years 1981 through 1991, with 1981 serving as
the base year.

A.3  EVALUATION OF DATA QUALITY

     The Current Industrial Report series is generally
considered a reliable source for quantities and values of
products shipped.  Monthly and annual data were estimated from
a sample designed to measure activities of the entire paints
and allied products industries.  Each annual report provides
data for 2 years, and figures from the 1991 report were used
for the coatings analyses.  In addition to the four
representative coatings products, the architectural coatings
Census category includes two other products:  architectural
lacquers and architectural coatings, not elsewhere
classified.  These categories were not included in the
estimates because of insufficient data.  However,  in 1991,
these two product categories combined represented only 1.3
percent of the total value of shipments for the architectural
coatings market.42    Statistics reported  in the Current
Industrial Reports at the seven-digit SIC product level are
based on Annual Surveys of Manufactures and represent about 95
percent of total shipments in the paint industry (SIC 2851)."
 To produce estimates for the entire industry, the Census
Bureau inflates the quantity and value figures reported in the
annual survey by a factor based on data reported by all
                             A-12

-------
establishments  in  the 1987 Census of Manufactures.1*  The
inflation factors  for architectural coating product  categories
are as follows:  1987 through 1991, 1.00;  1982  through 1986,
1.004; and for  1981,  1.04.c   Quantity and value figures for
the four product categories used in the demand  estimation are
inflated using  these  factors.  Prior to 1981, data were not
collected at  the more specific seven-digit SIC  level.   Using
the longer time series would provide more  data  points  but
would also preclude analysis of the individual  product
categories, and representativeness would be lost.
     The export data  used are the best publicly available;
however, combining export and domestic data to  estimate
domestic consumption  poses some problems.  The  classification
systems used  to gather both types of data  are different,  and
the corresponding  product categories used  cannot always be
compared.  For  example, data from the U.S. Department  of
Commerce publication  U.S. Imports for Consumption and  General
Imports, TSUSA  Commodity by Country of Origin were not used
because the imported  commodity classifications  had no
comparable domestic output classification.  Exclusion  of
imports from  the estimate of domestic consumption does not
pose a problem  because in 1991 the value of imports  for
architectural,  OEM, and special purpose coatings (SIC  28511,
28512, 28513) combined represented less than 0.9 percent of
the total domestic value of shipments.44  Data  from U.S.
Exports Schedule B Commodity by Country were available for
1981 through  1991,  and the export categories correspond well
     "The inflation factor for 1981 is based on 1977 Census relationships
and for 1982 through 1986  on 1982 Census relationships.
     "The 1991 quantities and values used in the model (values to impute
price) also include products in the special purpose and miscellaneous
allied paint products categories.  The special  purpose inflator for  1991 is
1.06, and the miscellaneous inflator in 1991 is 1.18.
                              A-13

-------
with the  four domestic product categories  except for 1989
through 1991.*5-«• «7-*8-49-«• "•«  In 1989, the  export codes and
categories changed and are no longer  compatible with the
domestic  categories.  In  addition, quantities  are reported  in
kilograms rather  than gallons, as  they  were in previous years.
For these reasons, export data were not used to adjust
domestic  consumption after 1988.   The GNP  data typically
represent income  for the  entire nation  including income
generated from American businesses located overseas.  The
current price data for the paint products  and  raw materials
should be considered reliable, though their accuracy may be
affected  by  the exclusion of imports  for the coatings products
and of exports and imports for the raw  materials prices.  CPIs
for all urban consumers with a base of  1982 through 1984 were
used in calculating real  prices.
     The  raw material prices used  are representative of the
entire U.S.  and export market for  these products, rather than
just the  U.S. supply to the paints and  coatings industry.  The
alkyd resins were used in this estimation  to represent an
input found  only  in solventborne coatings  and  acrylic resins
to represent an input found only in waterborne coatings.
However,  some acrylic resin materials are  used in some
solventborne coatings and alkyd resins  are used as modifiers
in waterbornes.   Exports  and imports  were  not  considered when
computing raw material supply prices  because foreign trade
data were not available for alkyd  and acrylic  resins.  In
1991, exports of  titanium dioxide  represented  17.9 percent of
the total domestic value  shipped and  imports were 10.9
percent."
                              A-14

-------
A.4  REFERENCES
1.
2.
3.

4.

5.



6.



7.



8.



9.



10



11



12.
U.S. Department of Commerce.  Current  Industrial Reports:
Paint and Allied Products,  1991.  Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office.   1992.

Industry Insights.  Architectural and  Industrial
Maintenance Surface Coatings  VOC Emissions  Inventory
Survey.  Prepared for  the National  Paint  and Coatings
Association in cooperation  with the AIM Regulatory
Negotiation Industry Caucus.  Final draft report.   1993.

Ref. 1.

Ref. 2.
Pindyck, Robert S., and Daniel L. Rubinfield.
Econometric Models and Economic Forecasts.  2nd Ed.
York, McGraw-Hill, Inc.  1981.
New
U.S. Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial Reports
Paints and Allied Products, 1982.  Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office.  1983.

U.S. Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial Reports:
Paints and Allied Products, 1983.  Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office.  1984.

U.S. Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial Reports:
Paints and Allied Products, 1984.  Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office.  1985.

U.S. Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial Reports:
Paints and Allied Products, 1985.  Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office.  1986.

U.S. Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial Reports:
Paints and Allied Products, 1986.  Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office.  1987.

U.S. Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial Reports:
Paints and Allied Products, 1987.  Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office.  1988.

U.S. Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial Reports:
Paints and Allied Products, 1988.  Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office.  1989.
                             A-15

-------
13.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial Reports:
     Paints and Allied Products, 1989.  Washington, DC:
     Government Printing Office.  1990.

14.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  Current Industrial Reports:
     Paints and Allied Products, 1990.  Washington, DC:
     Government Printing Office.  1991.

15.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  U.S. Exports Schedule B
     Commodity by Country.  FT446/Annual 1981.  1982.

16.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  U.S. Exports Schedule B
     Commodity by Country.  FT446/Annual 1982.  1983.

17.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  U.S. Exports Schedule B
     Commodity by Country.  FT446/Annual 1983.  1984.

18.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  U.S. Exports Schedule B
     Commodity by Country.  FT446/Annual 1984.  1985.

19.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  U.S. Exports Schedule B
     Commodity by Country.  FT446/Annual 1985.  1986.

20.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  U.S. Exports Schedule B
     Commodity by Country.  FT446/Annual 1986.  1987.

21.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  U.S. Exports Schedule B
     Commodity by Country.  FT446/Annual 1987.  1988.

22.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  U.S. Exports Schedule B
     Commodity by Country.  FT446/Annual 1988.  1989.

23.  U.S. Department of Labor.  Handbook of Labor Statistics.
     Bulletin 2340.  1989.

24.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  Survey of Current Business.
     v. 70, no. 7.  July 1990.

25.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  Survey of Current Business.
     v. 72 no. 7.  July 1992.

26.  U.S. Department of Commerce.  Survey of Current Business.
     v. 72, no. 12.  December 1992.

27.  Ref. 24.

28.  Ref. 25.

29.  Ref. 26.
                             A-16

-------
30.  U.S.  Department  of Commerce.   Current Construction
     Reports,  Housing Completions,  November 1992.   Washington,
     DC:   Government  Printing Office.   1993.

31.  U.S.  International Trade Commission.   Synthetic  Organic
     Chemicals, U.S.  Production and Sales,  1981.   USITC
     Publication  2470.   1982.

32.  U.S.  International Trade Commission.   Synthetic  Organic
     Chemicals, U.S.  Production and Sales,  1982.   USITC
     Publication  2470.   1983.

33.  U.S.  International Trade Commission.   Synthetic  Organic
     Chemicals, U.S.  Production and Sales,  1983.   USITC
     Publication  2470.   1984.

34.  U.S.  International Trade Commission.   Synthetic  Organic
     Chemicals, U.S.  Production and Sales,  1984.   USITC
     Publication  2470.   1985.

35.  U.S.  International Trade Commission.   Synthetic  Organic
     Chemicals, U.S.  Production and Sales,  1985.   USITC
     Publication  2470.   1986.

36.  U.S.  International Trade Commission.   Synthetic  Organic
     Chemicals, U.S.  Production and Sales,  1986.   USITC
     Publication  2470.   1987.

37.  U.S.  International Trade Commission.   Synthetic  Organic
     Chemicals, U.S.  Production and Sales,  1987.   USITC
     Publication  2470.   1988.

38.  U.S.  International Trade Commission.   Synthetic  Organic
     Chemicals, U.S.  Production and Sales,  1988.   USITC
     Publication  2470.   1989.

39.  U.S.  International Trade Commission.   Synthetic  Organic
     Chemicals, U.S.  Production and Sales,  1989.   USITC
     Publication  2470.   1990.

40.  U.S.  International Trade Commission.   Synthetic  Organic
     Chemicals, U.S.  Production and Sales,  1990.   USITC
     Publication  2470.   1991.

41.  U.S.  Department  of Commerce.   Current  Industrial Reports:
     Inorganic Chemicals, 1991.  Washington, DC:  Government
     Printing Office.    1992.

42.  Ref.  1.
                             A-17

-------
43.




44.




45.



46.



47.




48.



49.




50.



51.



52.



53.
Ref. 1.




Ref. 1.



Ref. 15



Ref. 16



Ref. 17



Ref. 18



Ref. 19



Ref. 20




Ref. 21



Ref. 22



Ref. 41
                             A-18

-------
                 APPENDIX B

SUMMARY OF REFORMULATION COST ESTIMATES FROM
               PUBLIC COMMENTS

-------
     At proposal, EPA's estimate for per product reformulation
cost was based on an estimate for a hypothetical new coating
included in a presentation to the Regulatory Negotiation
committee  (July 28, 1993).  This lump-sum cost estimate was
$250,000, implemented over three years at $83,333 per year.
     During the public comment period, EPA solicited public
input regarding the size and nature of reformulation costs to
gauge the reasonableness of (and potentially modify) the
estimate used in the EIA.  The public comments on costs were
reviewed for this purpose.  Costs were organized along the
following dimensions:

     •  technical staff  training
     •  prioritization of  products needing reformulation
     •  survey available materials
     •  reformulate  to desired properties
     •  performance  tests
     •  field tests
     •  marketing costs
     •  production costs  (labels)
     •  sales training
     •  executive expenses
                             B-l

-------
     Upon review of the public comments on costs, eleven of
the responses appeared to provide comparable  information for
estimating lump-sum reformulation costs per product.  Other
responses presented costs for all of the company's products,
but did not provide information on the number of products to
enable computation of  cost per product.  Other responses
could not be used either because of incompleteness or lack of
clarity about the information provided.  A list of and summary
statistics for the eleven potentially comparable responses
plus the original Regulatory Negotiation committee estimate
are presented in Table B-l.  Note that two of the estimates
are alternative interpretations of the same estimate.  One
interpretation estimates per-product cost by  dividing
the company's total cost estimate by all noncompliant
formulas.  The other interpretation is that the total cost
number is divided by the subset of formulas that are most
feasible to reformulate.  It was unclear from the comment,
which number the company used to estimate its total compliance
costs, so both interpretations were used to provide a range.
     Cost per product estimates (in 1991 dollars) range from
$576 to $272,000, with a mean value of $86,326.  The mean
value was rounded up to $87,000 to provide the model product
cost estimate used throughout the analysis.   As the summary
statistics in Table 2-1 indicate,  the central tendency cost
estimates  (mean and median) are well-below the $250,000 lump-
sum cost per product estimate used in the EIA at proposal,
ranging anywhere from 20 to 35 percent of that estimate.
     In summary, a review of the public comments related to
reformulation costs suggests that EPA may have significantly
overestimated the per-product costs by a factor of three to
five times at proposal.  Because it is based  on information
                              B-2

-------
        TABLE B-l.   REFORMULATION-RELATED  COST ESTIMATES
      Public Comment Docket Number
Estimated Cost
 per Product
  (current $)
Estimated Cost
 per Product
   ($ 1991)'
IV-D-217 (Interpretation 1,
Total cost divided by all noncompliant
products)
IV-D-217 (Interpretation 2,
Total cost divided by most feasible
reformulations)
IV-D-108
IV-D-110
IV-D-130
IV-D-93
IV-D-152
IV-D-36
IV-D-38
IV-F-le
IV-D-182
II-E-52

Summary statistics

N =
Min
Max
Mean
Median
     15,764

     48,220

     63,500
     13,000
     20,300
        656
    122,417
     51,210
    310,000
    150,000
     96,000
    267,000
     13,832

     42,311

     55,719
     11,407
     17,812
        576
    107,416
     44,935
    272,013
    131,619
     84,236
    254,038
                         12
                        576
                     272,013
                      86,326
                      50,327
a Converted from year in which estimate is given  (usually 1996)  to 1991
  using the Gross Domestic Product Price Deflator.
Source:  U.S.  Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, August
        1997.
provided  in the public comment period,  the revised estimate
used in this analysis should provide a more valid estimate of
reformulation-related costs  than the estimate used at
proposal.   Alternative methods for annual!zing the lump-sum
cost estimate of $87,000 are presented in the main text.
                                  B-3

-------
                        APPENDIX C

CALCULATION OF REGULATION-INDUCED COSTS WHEN REFORMULATION
          NORMALLY OCCURS AT FIXED TIME INTERVALS

-------
     One  complicating factor  in estimating the cost of the
regulation  is the fact that product reformulation is a normal
business  activity in the architectural  coatings  industry.
Therefore,  rather than viewing  the regulation as creating
reformulation responsibilities  (the maintained assumption
throughout  the analysis) , one might take the alternative view
that a  different time pattern of reformulation is created,
thereby leading to a lower estimate of  regulatory costs.  This
appendix  presents the issue analytically and develops a
numerical example to quantify the difference in costs under
the alternative assumptions.

     Suppose a company routinely reformulates products every
eight years.  If the average  product is  product midway through
its reformulation cycle, it will be reformulated four years in
the future  in the absence of  the regulation.  However,  the
regulation  requires them to do  the reformulation now rather
than four years in the future and this acceleration imposes
costs on  the firm.  To estimate  the costs  of this
acceleration, assume the initial reformulation cost of $87,000
occurs  in the first year.   Then  the net  present value,  today,
of a cost otherwise deferred  four years  into the future is

               NPV(-4)  = $87,000/1.07* = $66,372

Instead,  the company is required to  reformulate today at a
cost of
                              C-l

-------
                         NPV(O) = $87,000

The net effect on the company of accelerating the next
formulation is then

     Initial Net effect = NPV(-4) - NPV(O) = -$20,628

Thus, if the regulation just accelerates the next
reformulation, the one-time cost of that acceleration is
approximately $20,000.  This is substantially below the one-
time cost of $87,000 currently assumed in the EIA.  However,
if it is assumed that this requirement also forces all future
reformulations to be moved up four years, then the computation
must be expanded to measure the present value of the current
and all future adjustments.  To start, the present value of an
initial $87,000 cash expenditure repeated every eight years
thereafter can be written

          V(0) = $87,000 + $87,000*(l/( (1.07)" -  1))
               = $208, 139

Without the regulation, this stream of costs would be deferred
four years into the future.  Evaluating this in present value
terms gives

               V(-4)= V(0)/1.07* =  $158,788

Thus, the difference in present value between the two
reformulation cost streams is the total net effect of
accelerating this and all future reformulations.

          Total net effect = V(-4)  - V(0) = $49,351
                              C-2

-------
     This can be viewed as conceptually equivalent to a one-
time cost of the regulation for an average  product that is
over-the-limit.  This explicitly accounts for  the net present
value of the regulation's affect on all future formulations.
This one-time cost is substantially below the  $87,000 one-time
cost assumed in the analysis.

     By comparison, if the product were otherwise to be
reformulated one year in the future without the regulation,
the present value of this cost acceleration can be computed is
a similar fashion as $13,617 (16 percent of $87,000).  If the
previous reformulation had been implemented just one year
before the regulation, then the present value  of accelerating
the future reformulation cycle by seven years  would be $78,520
(90 percent of $87,000).

     In summary, the one-time cost estimate of an accelerated
reformulation schedule ranges from a small  fraction to a large
fraction of the reformulation cost estimate used in the EIA.
In this example, the average product's  one-time cost
equivalent is less than 60 percent of the estimate used in the
EIA.  Thus,  EPA contends that it has provided  a conservatively
high estimate of the true incremental cost  of  reformulating a
product subject to the regulation.
                              C-3

-------
             APPENDIX D

METHODOLOGY FOR COMPUTING MARKET AND
         WELFARE  ADJUSTMENTS

-------
D.I  METHODOLOGY FOR COMPUTING  SUPPLY  EFFECTS

     For the purposes of modeling  the  regulatory effects  in
each market, products are separated  into  four categories,
based on their producers' response to  the regulation:

     •  products  slated for withdrawal,
     •  products  on which exceedance fees are paid,
     •  products  slated for reformulation, and
     •  products  unconstrained by the regulation.

     The baseline  (preregulatory)  quantities from these groups
are denoted as follows:  Q*, Qr,  Q*, and Qa for groups 1,  2,  3,
and 4, respectively.  Total baseline market output equals the
sum of the four components:
                     Q = Q*  +  QF + Q* + Qu.                (D.I)

     Figure D-l depicts the aggregation of these subgroups
into a market supply function.   The regulation causes a shift
in the aggregate supply function depicted in Figure D-l as a
result of two phenomena:  an  inward supply shift due to
eliminating Group 1 through product withdrawals (e.g., the
shift from S° to  S1), and an upward supply shift due  to
imposing per-unit fees on the products from Group 2  (the shift
from S1  to  S1') .   There is no supply shift emanating from
                              D-l

-------
            P1

            Po
                                 Q-  QO
Q/t
 Figure D-l.  Single market  effects  of VOC content  regulation,
Group 3 because the reformulation  is assumed  not to affect

marginal production costs,  and there is no  shift from Group 4

because the unconstrained  products experience no regulation-

induced change  in their cost structure.  So the full

regulation-related shift is from S°  to  S1',  which leads to  a

new  market equilibrium.  At the new equilibrium,  price rises

to P'  and quantity falls to Q' .*
      "This graphical analysis demonstrates that the post-regulatory market
effects are uncertain if the analysis were to consider the possibility that
the reformulation process changes the marginal cost of producing the
coating as a result of changes in material or labor costs, for example.
This empirical issue can be resolved given sufficient data on the effect of
VOC content on production costs for all affected products.  Unfortunately,
these data were not available for this study, so the appropriate empirical
analysis could not be conducted to draw such conclusions.
                                 D-2

-------
D.2  DEMAND EFFECTS

     Figure D-l depicts a partial  equilibrium view of the
short-run effect of imposing content limits in one market.
One must also consider the  role  of substitute products in
determining the equilibrium adjustments,  which suggests a
multimarket perspective.  Figure D-2 depicts the markets for
two products  (A and B) that are  demand substitutes.   The price
of product B  factors  into product  A's demand function and vice
versa:

                       DA   =  DA(PA,  P.)                   (D.2)
                       DB   =  D^PB,  PA) .                  (D.3)

Given that A and B are substitutes implies

                         6DA / 5PB  >  0                     (D.4)
                            / 5PA > 0 .                   (D.5)
     Suppose the supply of A is  affected by the content  limits
in the manner described above, but  that the supply of  B  is
unaffected.  This initiates  a supply shift in market A from  SA°
to SAR.  Holding the  initial  demand  function constant,  this
shift would generate an equilibrium quantity of QA* and price
of PA".  However,  the associated price  increase in market A
induces an outward shift  in  the  demand  for product B,  which
raises the price of product  B.   Likewise,  the increase in B's
price leads to an outward shift  in  the  demand for  product A,
which raises its price and so on.   This interaction continues
until post-regulatory equilibrium is established at (PA*, Q/) ,
(PBR, QB*)-
                              D-3

-------
                                         Dj (Pg)
                         o; Q;
QAA
           $/Oi
                           Product A
                              08
                                         D(P)
                           Product B
Figure D-2.   Multiple market  effects of VOC regulations
                            D-4

-------
D.3   COMPUTING CHANGES IN EQUILIBRIUM PRICES AND QUANTITIES

      The  change in equilibrium prices and quantities for the
products  affected by the content limits and their substitutes
can be  numerically computed by adjusting the equations in the
multimarket  supply and demand system to reflect the imposition
of these  limits.   For each market,  i,  the equilibrium change
in quantity  supplied of each product affected by the
regulations  equals the sum of the supply changes from each of
the producer subgroups:

                 AQiS  = AQiX +  AQ/ +  AQi"  + AQi".            (D.6)

The change  (from baseline)  in quantity supplied by the
withdrawal sector is  simply the negative of the quantity
originally supplied by that group:

                          AQiX  =  - Qix.                      (D.7)

      The  change in quantity supplied from the fee-paying
sector  is specified as follows:

                    AQ/ = e/JQi'/Pi) (APt  -  Ft)               (D.8)

where ej  is  the supply elasticity of the fee producers in
market  i, APt is the change in equilibrium market price, and
other terms  are as  previously  defined  (without the
subscripts).  APA- Fx  is  the change  in  "net price'  for the fee-
paying producers  (i.e.,  the change  in unit process  less  the
unit  fee).

     The changes  in quantity supplied from the reformulating
group and unconstrained groups,  respectively,  are
                              D-5

-------
                                                           (D.9)
                      AQiU =  elu(Qi°/P)AP1.                 (D.10)

     These producers respond to the  increase  in price with no
counteracting effect on costs.  Given  the  higher price in the
post-regulatory equilibrium, output  will increase  from these
two groups of producers.

     The aggregate change in equilibrium supply quantity can
now be restated by combining the preceding five equations:

         AQ,S = - Q/ + e/tQ/XPi) (AP.-FJ  + e/fQjVPJ APi
                                                          (D.ll)
     The change in market demand  for  each product  is  given by

               AQiD =   Eu(Qi /PJAP,. + Ei-jCQi/PjjAPj         (D.12)

where Eu is  the own-price demand  elasticity for product,  i and
Eij is the associated  cross-price  demand elasticity between
products i and j .  Consumer demand theory supports  the
assertion that own-price elasticities are negative  and  that
cross-price  elasticities of substitutes  are positive.   To
attain equilibrium, the change in quantity  demanded must equal
the change in quantity supplied in both  markets:
     This provides a system of M*3 equations in M*3 unknowns,
where M equals the number of markets affected by the
regulation.  This can be reduced to an M*2 equation system,
simply by substituting AQiD = AQiS = AQi.  This system can be
solved simultaneously to compute the change in equilibrium
price and change in equilibrium quantity for each market.  To
                              D-6

-------
do this, baseline market data, model parameters  (supply and
demand elasticities), and an empirical characterization of the
various supply shocks alluded to above are needed.

D.4  COMPUTING WELFARE EFFECTS

     Changes in the market equilibrium cause changes in
resource allocation, which, when quantified, provide measures
of how the welfare costs of the regulation are distributed
across groups affected by the regulation.  The groups focused
upon here are architectural coatings producers and consumers,
because the changes in prices and quantities directly affect
their welfare.  Since fee payments are considered, the
government sector is also included in the welfare analysis
because they collect the fee revenues.  This study does not
measure the welfare benefits of reductions in VOC emissions, a
value against which these costs may be measured to determine
the net value to society of the proposed regulatory structure.

D.4.1     Effects on Architectural Coatings Producers

     The profits earned at the new equilibrium to the profits
earned at the old equilibrium can be compared as a measure of
effects of the regulation on the individual producer.
Foregone baseline profits (n°)  provide a  measure  of  the  loss
to producers that choose to exit rather than reformulate:

                      An = nR* - n° = -n°.                 (D.14)

For the remaining producers, the change in profits is affected
by several factors, including the incurrence of the fixed
reformulation cost and any associated changes in price,
quantity,  and marginal cost.
                              D-7

-------
     The remaining firms' costs may be affected through either
the reformulation cost or the fee payment. The effect of the
content limit on producers is generally not uniform and thus
raises some distributional considerations.  As indicated
above, shifts in the aggregate supply function will cause the
market price to rise.  For some producers, the benefits of the
price increase may outweigh the net costs of compliance. This
is certainly the case for producers of coatings with VOC
content below the regulatory standards, because they incur no
reformulation costs but would gain from the rise in market
price sparked by the compliance costs and/or product
withdrawals incurred by their competitors.  Alternatively,
fixed reformulation costs may be substantial for some
producers, outweighing the positive price effect.  The profit
effect will be negative for those producers.  Other producers
may fall in the midrange, where the price benefits and cost
effects essentially offset each other.

     Changes in producer welfare are generally reported as
changes in producer surplus.  The aggregate change in producer
surplus for the withdrawn-product producers equals the sum of
forgone profits from all withdrawn products in market i:
The j subscript indicates forgone profits from the j'th
product in market i.  NAA  is  the  number of withdrawn products
in market i.  The change in producer surplus from the
reformulating sector can be approximated as follows:
                              D-8

-------
APi  is the change in equilibrium price, AQ/ is the change in
equilibrium quantity from  the  reformulating producers,  Qi* is
the initial quantity of the  reformulating  producers,  R,c is  the
annualized reformulation costs,  and NtR is  the number of
products needing reformulation.

     The change in producer  surplus for the fee-paying
producers is initially computed  as  follows:
          APS/1 = (APi-FJMQ/ + AQ/J-O.S'AQ/MAPi-Fi) .    (D.17)

The first term reflects  the  net revenue  effects  of  the price
rise less the fee payment  and  the second term reflects changes
in deadweight loss.  To  this term we  must add the fixed  cost
(per product) associated with  fee recordkeeping  requirements
so that the full welfare effect is
                     APS/  =  APS/1  - FF •  Ni               (D.18)

where FF is the fixed cost per product of fee recordkeeping
and Ni equals the number of products subject to the fee in
market i .
     Finally, the change in  producer  surplus  for unconstrained
producers is
                     = APi  •  Qiu +  0.5  • AQiU • APi          (D.19)
with the Qi° reflecting  the quantity supplied by these
producers.  Total  (net) producer  surplus effects is simply the
sum of the terms above:
                  i = APSiX + APS^  +  PS/ +  APSt°.          (D.20)
                              D-9

-------
D.4.2     Effects on Architectural Coatings Consumers

     Changes in consumer welfare are measured by the change in
consumer surplus, which quantifies losses due to a combination
of the higher price and reduced consumption quantity.  This
change can be approximated as follows:

            ACSj. = -APi •  (Qi + AQi)  +  0.5 • APi •  AQi.      (D.21)

D.4.3     Effects on the Government Sector

     The transfer of fees from the fee-paying producers to the
recipient of those fees must be considered.  For the purposes
of the welfare analysis, the government is identified as the
"recipient" of the fees.

                    AGSi = Fi • (Q/ + AQ/) .               (D.22)

     Ultimately, the government may choose to redistribute
those fees back to affected producers or consumers or back to
other members of society via the Treasury; however, for
purposes of quantifying these distributional flows, they are
assigned as gains to the government sector.

D.4.4     Net Welfare Effects

     The net welfare effects are computed by taking the sum of
producer, consumer, and government surplus:
                              + ACSj. + AGSi.              (D.23)

This calculation nets out any transfers from one group to
another within society (e.g., transfers from consumers to
producers through higher prices and transfers of fee revenues
                             D-10

-------
from producers to the government) because these transfers do
not affect the total sum of resource costs, just how they are
distributed within society.  AWFi provides an estimate  of the
net social costs of the regulation.
                             D-ll

-------