SEFft
             United States
             Environmental Protection.
             Agency
             Office of Water Regulations
             and Standards
             Washington, DC 20460
EPA-440/2-82-009
October 1982
             Water
Economic Analysis of
Proposed  Effluent Standards
and  Limitations for the
Pesticide Industry
                        QUANTITY

-------
    ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS OF PROPOSED EFFLUENT
STANDARDS AND LIMITATIONS FOR THE PESTICIDES INDUSTRY
              Economic  Impact  Analysis

                    Prepared for

        U.  S.  Environmental Protection Agency
          Office of Analysis and Evaluation
                Washington, DC  20460
                         by

                  Meta Systems Inc
              Cambridge, Massachusetts
                    November 1982

-------
                                   Preface
    The attached document is a contractor's study prepared for the Office
of Water Regulations and Standards of the Environmental Protection Agency
("EPA").  The purpose of the study is to analyze the economic  impact  which
could result from the application of alternative BPT, BCT, BAT,  PSES,  NSPS
and PSNS limitations and standards established under the  Federal Water
Pollution control Act  (the Act), as amended.

    The study supplements the  technical study  ("EPA Development  Document")
supporting the proposal of regulations under the Act.  The Development
Document surveys existing and  potential waste  treatment control  methods
and technology within particular industrial source categories  and  supports
proposed limitations based upon an analysis of the feasibility of  these
limitations in accordance with the requirements of the Act.  Presented in
the Development Document are the investment and operating costs  associated
with various alternative control and treatment technologies.   The  attached
document supplements this analysis by estimating  the broader economic
effects which might result from the required application  of various
control methods and technologies.  This study  investigates  the effect of
alternative approaches  in terms of price  increases/ effects upon
employment and the continued viability of affected plants,  and other
competitive effects.

    The study has been  prepared with the  supervision and  review  of the
Office of Analysis and  Evaluation of the  EPA.  This report  was submitted
in fulfillment of Contract No. 68-01-6426, by  Meta Systems  Inc.  This
report  reflects work completed as of November  1982.

    This report is being released and circulated  at approximately  the same
time as publication in  the Federal Register of a  notice of  proposed  rule
making.  It will be considered along with the  information contained  in the
Development Document and any comments received by  EPA on  either  document
before or during proposed rule making proceedings necessary to establish
final regulations.

-------
                              Table  of Contents


                                                                   Page No.

Section 1;  Executive Summary

Economic Assessment Methodology 	   1-1
Industry Profile	   1-3
Recommended Treatment Technologies  and Costs	   1-4
Economic Impact Analysis	   1-6
Small Business Analysis	1-11
Impact of New Source Standards  (NSPS  and PSNS)	1-13
Limits of the Analysis	1-13

Section 2;  The Economic Assessment Methodology

Industry-Level Impacts:  Price, Output, Profits,
   Employment	   2-1
Plant Impact Analysis:  Closure 	  2-10
New Source Standards	2-13

Section 3;  Industry Profile

Structure of Demand	   3-1
Structure of Supply	 . .  .   3-5
Profitability 	  3-15
Research and Development	3-15
Imports and Exports	3-16
Industry Outlook	3-20

Section 4;  Recommended Treatment Technologies and Associated Costs

Cost Methodology	   4-2
Treatment Options	   4-4
Treatment Cost Estimates	   4-9

Section 5;  Economic Impact Analysis

Industry-Level Analysis of Impacts on the Pesticide
   Chemicals Industry 	   5-1
Plant-Specific Impact Analysis	5-13

Appendices;

A.  Plant and Firm Data Ordered by Firm Employment
       and Firm Sales	  .   A-l
B.  Derivation of Capital Recovery Factor 	   B-l
C.  References	   C-l

-------
                               List of Tables
                                                                   Page No.

1-1   Total Cumulative Costs of Compliance for Indirect
         and Direct Treatment Levels and Economics Options
         (millions of 1982 dollars)	   1-7
1-2   Industry-Level Analysis Summary 	 ........   1-9
1-3   Summary of Plant-Level Impacts. ... 	  1-10
1-4   Summary of Closures Due to Treatment Costs	1-12
1-5   Results of Closure Analysis for Economic Options	1-12
1-6   Effect of Screening Criterion on Number of Plants
         Identified as Severely Impacted	1-15

2-1   Baseline Average Pesticide Costs and Price, 1978	   2-3
2-2   Pesticide Price and Cost Indices	   2-4

3-1   Total U.S. Pesticide Chemicals Production
         (1967-1978)	   3-2
3-2   Estimated Composition of U.S. Pesticide Chemicals
         Production in 1977	   3-5
3-3   U.S. Herbicide Production (1967-1980) 	   3-6
3-4   U.S. Insecticide Production  (1967-1980) 	   3-7
3-5   U.S. Fungicide Production (1967-1980) 	   3-8
3-6   Raw Materials and Key Chemical Intermediates
         Used in Pesticide Manufacture	3-10
3-7   Pesticide Market by Producer, 1980	3-11
3-8   Profile of Pesticide Plants—Subcategorization	3-12
3-9   Pesticide Production and Capacity Utilization in 1979  	  3-14
3-10  U.S. Production and Trade in Herbicides	3-17
3-11  U.S. Production and Trade in Insecticides	3-18
3-12  U.S. Production and Trade in Fungicides	3-19
3-13  Annual Growth Rates for Volume and
         Value of Pesticide Exports  (1969-1977) 	  3-20
3-14  Pesticide Market by Major Class—
         Yearly Rate of Growth (1980-1985)	3-21

4-1   Present Wastewater Treatment and Estimated Treatment
         Required for Compliance with Effluent Limitations	   4-6
4-2   Incremental Treatment Costs for Affected
         Pesticides Plants  	  4-10
4-3   Total Cumulative Costs of Compliance for Indirect
         and Direct Treatment Levels and Economics Options
         (millions of 1979 dollars)	4-12
4-4   Total Cumulative Costs of Compliance for Indirect
         and Direct Treatment Levels and Economic Options
         (millions of 1982 dollars)	  4-13
4-5   Unit Treatment Costs for Contract Hauling and
         Evaporation for Formulator/Packagers 	  4-15
4-6   New Source Model Plant Treatment Costs	4-18
                                      11

-------
                               List of Tables
                                 (continued)
                                                                   Page No.
5-1   Baseline Cost and Price Projections	   5-2
5-2   Industry-Level Annalysis Summary	   5-4
5-3   Herbicide Baseline Projections	   5-6
5-4   Insecticide Baseline Projections	   5-7
5-5   Fungicide Baseline Projections .  .... 	   5-8
5-6   1985 Industry-Level Summary Effect of Treatment
         Options on Production.	   5-9
5-7   Summary of Baseline and Impact Projection;
         Production and Prices for Economic Option 1
         and Case A:  Average Cost Passthrough	5-10
5-8   Relationship Between Employment and Shipments
         for SIC Group 28694	5-11
5-9   1985 Industry-Level Summary Effect
         of Treatment Options on Employment 	  5-12
5-10  Total Cumulative Costs of Compliance for Formulator/
         Packagers	5-13
5-11  Costs of Producting Major Crops—1977
         Percent	5-14
5-12  Annualized Costs as a Percentage of Sales 	  5-16
5-13  Summary of Plants Incurred by Treatment Costs	5-19
5-14  Summary of Plants Severely Impacted by Treatment Costs	  5-22
5-15  Summary of Closure Analysis for Economic Options	5-23
5-16  Summary of Closure Analysis 	  5-24
5-17  Results of Small Business Analysis:  Economic Option 1 .  ...  5-26
5-18  Types of Pesticides and Price Ranges by Subcategory 	  5-28
5-19  Value of Pesticide Production of Model Plants 	  5-29
5-20  Summary of NSPS Treatment Costs on Price of Pesticides	  5-31
5-21  Summary of PSNS Treatment Costs on Price of Pesticides	5-32
5-22  Pesticide Production and Capacity Utilization, 1979 	  5-33
                                     iii

-------
                               List  of  Figures






                                                                    Page No.




3-1   Annual Pesticide Production by Product  Type 	    3-4
                                      IV

-------
                                  Section 1

                              Executive Summary
    This study analyzes the economic impact of water pollution controls  on
the Pesticides Industry.  This study was prepared under  the  supervision  of
the Office of Analysis and Evaluation, U.S. Environmental  Protection  Agency.
As required by the Clean Water Act, this study presents  for  consideration
the economic impacts of regulations proposed under  the Act which  would con-
trol the industry's discharge of its effluents.  The regulations  analyzed
are Best Available Technology Economically Achievable  (BAT),  Pretreatment
Standards for Existing Standards (PSES), New Source Performance Standards
(NSPS), and Pretreatment Standards for New Sources  (PSNS).

    The impacts analyzed are:  total costs of compliance,  changes in
price, output, profits and employment, plant closures, and investment in
new capacity.
Economic Assessment Methodology

    The major elements of the assessment methodology  include  industry-  level
impacts for price, output, employment and profit, a plant-level closure
analysis for plants that incur wastewater treatment and  solid waste  removal
costs, an assessment of costs to meet new source  standards  and an  analysis
of impacts on small businesses as  required by  the Regulatory  Flexibility  Act.
    Industry-Level  Impacts;  Price, Output, Profits,  Employment,  Total
    Costs of Compliance

    The industry-level analysis estimates  the  impacts of  the proposed
effluent guidelines on three major product groups  in  the  industry:
herbicides, insecticides, and fungicides,  and  on the  industry as  a  whole.
Impacts are estimated for prices, production,  employment, and profits.
The basic approach  is to make a baseline forecast  of  these variables in
the absence of the proposed effluent guidelines and then  to estimate the
changes resulting from the increase in production  costs attributable to
the guidelines.

    The methodology utilizes a cost-price  submodel and a  demand-production
submodel.  The cost-price submodel was developed to disaggregate  pesticide
prices into a profit component and several cost components.  The  cost-price
submodel is used to predict the price at which pesticide  chemicals  will be
supplied to users.  For the baseline, the cost components do not  include
additional treatment costs whereas the impact  projection  includes the
treatment costs.

    The economic impact analysis examines  two  possible price responses of
the industry to added treatment costs.  The first  (Case A) is that  the
price increase equals the average cost increase due to treatment  require-
ments for all plants in the industry.  Note that this does not imply that
all costs are passed through in the form of higher prices, since  the
average includes those plants which do not incur any  additional costs.

-------
The second assumption  (Case B) is that no price  increase occurs  and  the
industry absorbs the entire amount of treatment costs as a  reduction in
profits.  These assumptions were selected because only  a fraction  of the
plants in the industry incur added treatment costs, making  it unlikely
that all costs can be passed through in the form of higher  prices.

    A demand-production submodel was developed to estimate  quantities of
pesticides chemicals that will be used given the two sets of projected
prices; i.e., baseline conditions and conditions with standards  imposed.
This model relates pesticide demand to its major determinants,  including
agricultural acreage, the fraction treated by pesticides, the rate of ap-
plication, and the pesticide price.  With treatment costs passed through,
pesticide prices are increased which alters the demand  and, in turn,  the
production quantities.  The derivation of the two submodels is discussed
next.

    Employment and profit impacts are estimated from the impacts on  output
and coefficients for average employees and profit per unit  of output.
Total costs of compliance are found simply by summing the estimates  of
costs of compliance made by the Technical Contractor for individual  plants.
    Plant-Level Impacts;  Closure

    Costs of various wastewater treatment levels were developed  by  the
Technical Contractor on a plant-by-plant basis.  The costs are expressed
on an annualized basis and compared to the value of pesticide produced  at
each plant.  A ratio of four percent annualized cost to value of production
was used as a screening criterion and those plants which  equal or exceed
four percent are considered to be severely impacted.

    The severely impacted plants were analyzed  in terms of product  lines,
quantities and value of pesticides and other products made at the plant,
period of production during the year and parent company ownership.   Lacking
plant-specific financial information, the above factors were used to arrive
at qualitative judgments about plant and product line shutdowns,  first
considering only the effects of additional wastewater treatment  costs.

    Plant closures are estimated both for a baseline case and for the
incremental impacts of the proposed effluent guidelines.  Costs  of  com-
pliance with hazardous solid waste management rules under the Resource
Conservation and Recovery Act  (RCRA) are included as part of the baseline,
because these rules have already been promulgated, but their compliance
costs have not otherwise been incorporated into the data  base.   Because
impacts due to RCRA may be significant, it is important to identify them
before determining the incremental impacts of the proposed effluent guide-
lines.  Specifically, if a plant is predicted to close due to RCRA  costs
alone, then it cannot be counted as part of the incremental impact  of the
proposed effluent guidelines, even if those compliance costs are also high.
                                     1-2

-------
    Small Business Analysis

    An analysis is conducted to determine whether  small  firms  bear
disproportionate impacts under the proposed effluent guidelines.  The
method used is to classify all firms in the data sample  as  either large  or
small and then to compare the distribution of impacts on plants belonging
to firms in the two sets.  The impacts include number of plants with com-
pliance costs, the distribution of the cost to sales ratio, and the number
of closures.

    We have defined small businesses to be those having  less than $10 million
in annual sales.  Eighteen out of the 80 plants in the data base, 23 percent
of the total, fall under this definition of a small business.
    New Source Standards

    Costs of treatment for new plants were estimated  for  direct  and  indirect
dischargers by the Technical Contractor.  Model plants were  identified  to
develop high and low estimates of capital and annual  0 &  M costs.  Annualized
treatment costs were calculated and compared to pesticide prices.  In addi-
tion to assessing cost effects on pesticide prices, an analysis  was  made  to
determine if new production capacity is likely to be  needed  by 1985.  This
is based on current capacity, recent production levels and projected growth
of pesticide use.
Industry Profile

    The pesticide industry encompasses the production of pesticide  chemicals
and the formulation of those chemicals into useable  forms.   Both  the  pro-
ducers of the active  ingredients and the formulators of the  end-use products
are defined as being  part^of the broader organic chemicals industry.

    There are three major product groups within the  pesticides  industry:
herbicides, insecticides and fungicides.  Other product groups  include
plant growth regulators, rodenticides, soil-conditioners and fumigants.
Production of herbicides is currently greater  than that of insecticides  or
fungicides, but the relative production dominance of the three  pesticides
types has varied over the past two decades.  While herbicides production
has experienced the most rapid growth since 1960, it did not take the lead
until 1975 when 788 million pounds were produced.  This compared  in the
same year to about 660 million pounds of insecticides and 155 million
pounds of fungicides.  In 1980, about 805 million pounds of  herbicides
valued at $2.7 billion were produced.  In the  same year, 506 million
pounds of insecticides, valued at $1.3 billion, were produced and about
156 million pounds of fungicides, valued at $0.3 billion.

    Both real and nominal prices of all pesticides have risen since 1967.
Prices are heavily dependent on oil prices with the  most dramatic increases
                                     1-3

-------
occurring between 1974 and 1975 when average prices  (in current dollars)
of pesticide ingredients increased 47 percent.  Prices were  180 percent
higher in 1980 than they were in 1970, however in terms of real prices
(1967 index = 100) the change between 1970 and 1980 was less than  45
percent.

    Prior to 1970, the formulation of pesticides was carried out by a  large
and diverse group of independent formulators and farm cooperatives, but  in
the mid-1970's chemical producers started to move into the formulating
business.  This trend of forward integration has continued and by  one
estimate, 80 percent of the formulated pesticides industry is controlled by
chemical producers.22  The pesticides industry currently  is  dominated  by
large chemical and pharmaceutical firms.  The manufacturing  of pesticides
generally requires considerable capital, not only to build and operate
plants, but also to undertake the research and testing that  is required
before a new pesticide can be marketed.  Due to large capital requirements
the barriers to new firms' entering the pesticide industry are considerable.
Based on total value of industry production, eight firms  account for about
80 percent of the market.15

    Research and development is an essential part of the  industry; the
costs of R & D have risen considerably over the past ten  years and are
expected to continue to increase.  A large part of the R&D cost increase
has been attributed to federal regulations that pertain to the production
and testing of pesticides.  A likely consequence of continued increases  in
R&D costs will be further concentration of the industry.  Dominant firms
in the pesticide industry are likely to be -those with existing expertise
(in screening, testing and compliance with registration requirements), in
particular, the pharmaceutical companies.

    The use of pesticides is expected to grow over the next  five years.
The three major product types that make up the pesticide  industry  are
expected to grow at different rates during the 1980-1985  period, with  the
value of herbicides growing at the highest annual rate  (8.6  percent) and
the value of insecticides growing at the lowest annual rate  (7.8 percent).
Recommended Treatment Technologies and Costs
    Direct and Indirect Dischargers

    Treatment technologies were evaluated by the Technical Contractor  so
that they might be applied, singly or in combination, to achieve  the
required reduction of pollutants  at each plant.  These  technologies are  as
follows:
                                     1-4

-------
                           Treatment Technologies

                           Steam stripping
                           Filtration
                           Chemical Oxidation
                           Activated carbon
                           Biological treatment
                           Metals separation
                           Resin adsorption
                           Hydrolysis

These technologies can be classified into four major  groups:  physical-
chemical treatment, biological treatment, multimedia  filtration,  and
carbon filtration.  One or more of the technologies listed  were  selected
for each manufacturing plant  (based on wastewater characteristics and
treatment currently in place) and this selection defined  a  limited number
of treatment options.  To achieve different levels of- effluent treatment,
the options for each plant are combined to define several treatment levels.
For the indirect dischargers, the treatment levels are designated as
follows:

       Level 1:  physical/chemical treatment,
       Level 2:  Level 1 plus biological treatment

For direct dischargers, the designated treatment levels are:

       Level 1:  physical/chemical and biological treatment,
       Level 2:  Level 1 plus multimedia filtration,
       Level 3:  Level 2 plus carbon filtration.

Capital investment and annual costs were estimated for the  two pretreatment
treatment levels and three direct discharge treatment levels.  The options
and costs were developed in incremental terms:  for indirect dischargers,
the second pretreatment treatment level includes the  first  and for direct
dischargers, each subsequent treatment level includes the technologies of
the preceding treatment level.

    Annualized treatment costs are computed from capital  and annual costs
by converting the capital cost to an annual equivalent and  adding it to
O&M costs.  Capital costs are converted to an annual  equivalent  by multi-
plying by a capital recovery factor (.218) based on the assumptions of a
ten year equipment life, a 13 percent cost of capital, and  a five year
depreciation life; the derivation is shown in Appendix B.   The annual
equivalent of the capital cost is added to the estimated  annual  operating
and maintenance (O&M) cost to calculate an annualized cost.

    The total cumulative costs for the various treatment  levels  defined
above are shown in Table 1-1 in 1982 dollars.  The costs  presented for
each treatment level include costs associated with each lower level of
treatment, e.g., costs for direct dischargers, Level  2 includes  costs for
BAT Level 1.
                                     1-5

-------
    The treatment levels for direct and indirect dischargers are combined
to form economic options which are defined as follows:
                               Direct             Indirect
           Economic          Discharger          Discharger
            Option              Level               Level

               111
               221
               3                  3                   1

               412

               522

               632

    The treatment costs for each economic option are shown as part of
Table 1-1.


    NSPS and PSNS

    The Technical Contractor has also specified treatment levels for
direct discharger and indirect discharger new sources for each of the ten
subcategories  (NSPS and PSNS, respectively).  Pesticides were assigned to
subcategories based on several considerations, including raw materials
used in manufacturing, wastewater characteristics and treatability, and
disposal and manufacturing processes.  Wastewater treatment trains that
meet new source standards were synthesized for each subcategory.  The
treatment level for NSPS corresponds to treatment Level 1 for direct
dischargers and the treatment level for PSNS corresponds to treatment
Level 1 for indirect dischargers.


Economic Impact Analysis


    Industry-Level Impacts;  Price, Output, Employment, Profit

    Baseline and impact projections for the herbicides, insecticides and
fungicides markets were made using the production projections, cost data,
and price data available for each category.  Impacts vary among the three
categories of pesticides due to differing costs of treatment and different
average prices.  The elasticity of demand is assumed to be the same for
each category as is the number of employees per pound of production.
                                     1-6

-------
           Table 1-1.  Total Cumulative Costs of Compliance  for
         Indirect and Direct Treatment Levels and  Economic Options
                         (millions of 1982 dollars)


Indirect Discharger
Subcategories 1-12
Level 1
Level 2
Formulator/Packagers*
Level 1
Level 2
Total
Level 1
Level 2
Direct Discharger
Level 1
Level 2
Level 3
Economic Option
Subcategories 1-12
1
2
3
4
5
6
Formulator/Packagers
1-6
1 Capital
I Costs


15.8
58.0

46.8
46.8

62.5
104.8

30.1
35.9
j 51.4


45.9
51.7
67.2
88.1
93.9
109.5

46.8
1 Annual
I O&M Cost


7.4
14.8

3.2
3.2

10.6
18.0

19.0
20.1
, 36.9


26.4
27.5
44.3
33.8
34.9
51.7

1 3'2
I Annualized
I Cost


10.8
27.5

13.5
13.5

24.3
( 40.9

25.5
28.0
• 48.1


36.3
38.7
58.9
53.0
55.4
75.6

. 13.5
   * Formulator/Packagers  (Subcategory 13) are handled separately due to
differences in the way data were aggrregated for this subcategory as
opposed to Subcategories 1 through 12,
                                     1-7

-------
    A comparison of the baseline and impact analyses indicates  that  the
impact of additional treatment costs if passed through, would be  to  raise
pesticide prices, reduce demand because of the higher prices, and reduce
production, profits and employment as a result of  the reduced demand.
Table 1-2 shows the overall industry impacts for price increase and  profit
reduction for each treatment level and option in 1982 dollars.  On a per-
centage basis such costs are estimated to be relatively insignificant.
Prices for the industry as a whole will rise 0.19  to 1.36 percent
(depending on the economic options) and profits will fall 0.08  to 0.59
percent.

    If additional treatment costs are absorbed by  pesticide manufacturers,
prices and production are the same as in the baseline projection  but
profits will decrease by 2.0 to 12.0 percent depending on the economic
option selected.
    Plant Specific Impact Analysis

    A plant by plant analysis was made to identify those plants  that  might
be affected by new treatment standards.  Up to 51 of  the 117 plants  that
produce pesticides would incur some added costs, depending on  the  economic
option.  The annualized treatment costs were calculated as a percent  of
the value of pesticides produced at each plant.  As an  initial screening
step, those plants with treatment costs less than four  percent  of
pesticide value were screened out.  Use of the criterion does  not  mean
that plants below this level are unaffected; however, plant-specific
financial data are not available to investigate the capability of  each
plant to absorb externally imposed treatment costs.   Therefore,  plants
with treatment costs of four percent or more of pesticide value  are  judged
to be severely impacted.  The total number of such plants  (direct  and
indirect dischargers) may be as high as 26 depending  on the economic
option.  Table 1-3 shows the number of plants with incremental costs  and
the distribution of the cost/sales ratio for each treatment level.

    To carry out an analysis of possible plant closures or product line
shutdowns, a profile of the pesticide plants was developed.  About 50
percent of the 117 plants formulate and package pesticides as  well as
produce the active chemical ingredients, 75 percent produce chemicals
other than pesticides, 20 percent produce pesticides  throughout  the year
and another 20 percent produce pesticides during fewer  than 30 days  a
year.  Also, 50 percent of the plants specialize in the production of one
pesticide and 95 percent produce no more than four.   While 12  of the
plants produce 50 percent of the total value of pesticides, the  value of
output for almost half of the plants is less than $5  million annually.

    A qualitative analysis of each severely impacted  plant was conducted
in order to judge which ones were likely candidates for plant  closure or
discontinuation of the pesticide product line.   (This analysis contains
confidential information about pesticide producers and  is not  included in
                                     1-8

-------
0

41


5  2
          01


          Q

          •o
          C
          (13 O

          jj u
          o ->
          V 6
          " Q

          r>
          i§
          K>
            a
            <*
                                                                Ci
                                                                0'
                                      •o

                                       u
                                               si
                                                                ml
                                                                Qi
                            _ ^    jj  O
                            —i  in    
-------
                 Table 1-3.   Summary of Plant-Level Impacts
                      [Plants With I Distribution of Cost/Sales Ratio in Percent
                      I Incremental I             (Number of Plants)
                      I    Costs   I     0-1%   |	1-2%  1   2-4%  I	Over 4%
Indirect Dischargers

   Level 1                 16

   Level 2                 34

Direct Dischargers

   Level 1                 15

   Level 2                 18

   Level 3            ,     18
1

6




2

5

3
4

3




2

2

2
3

6




5

5

5
 8

19




 6

 6

 8
                                    1-10

-------
this report.)  If a plant was predicted to close  due  to  RCRA compliance
costs, this was counted as a baseline closure, since  that  Act has  already
been promulgated.  Incremental closures under  each  treatment level are
defined as closures resulting from  the sum of  RCRA  and BAT or PSES costs
for those plants which are not baseline closures.   Table 1-4 shows the
results of the closure analysis for each treatment  level.   Separate
results are shown for plant and product line closures.   (In the  latter
case, only a portion of the plant is expected  to  close.)

    No plants and three product lines are predicted to be  closures in the
baseline case which accounts for $0.7 million  of  pesticide product value.
Under Level 1 for indirect dischargers there are  two  plants and  five  pro-
duct line closures, for a total pesticide product value  of $20.8 million or
0.6 percent of the industry product value.  Under Level  1  treatment for
direct dischargers, there are one plant and two product  line closures,  for
a total pesticide product value of  $12.4 million  or 0.3  percent  of the
industry product value.  With Level 2 for indirect  dischargers,  plant
closures are six and product line closures are eight  with  a combined
product value of $64.8 million or 1.6 percent  of  the  industry value.
Levels 2 and 3 do not increase closures of the direct discharge  plants.

    The aggregate effects of treatment combinations are  shown in Table
1-5.   (The values shown account for one plant  that  is both an indirect  and
direct discharger and therefore included under direct and  indirect treat-
ment levels in Table 1-4.)  Under economic option 1,  2,  or 3 (i.e.,
indirect discharger treatment Level 1 and any  of  the  direct discharge
treatment levels) there are three plant and seven product  line closures;
total value of pesticide production of these is $25.1 million or 0.7
percent of the industry total.  Under economic options 4,  5, or  6  plant
closures are seven, product line closures are  ten and their total  value of
$69.1 million is 1.7 percent of the total industry  value.
Small Business Analysis

    This section analyzes  the  relative  impact of  the  proposed  effluent
guidelines on small and large  firms to  determine  if small  firms  face
disproportionate impacts.  Based on the discussion  in the  methodology
section, small firms are defined as those having  less than $10 million  in
annual sales.  Since it was not possible to obtain  sales data  for  all
firms, the results are presented for a  sample of  80 plants for which this
data is available for the  parent firm from the Dun  and Bradstreet  data
base.  This sample is a large  fraction  of the total number of  117  plants
which comprise the definition  of the pesticide industry used in  this study
and includes many plants owned by small firms, so the results  are  not
likely to differ much from those for the entire pesticide  industry.

    Using the definition of small businesses given above,  18 out of the
sample of 80 plants belong to  small firms.  The results indicate that
                                    1-11

-------
           Table 1-4.  Summary of Closures Due to Treatment Costs
                               No. of
                              Closures
                [Value of Pesticide Production Lost
     Control Levels
Plant |  Product
      I    Line
                   I   Percent of Total
        Million $  I    Industry Value
Baseline Case*

Indirect Dischargers

  Level 1

  Level 2

Direct Dischargers
  2

  6
5

8
 0.7



20.8

64.8
0.01



0.6

1.6
Level 1
Level 2
Level 3
1
1
1 L 1
2
2
2 1
12.4
12.4
1 12'4 1
0.3
0.3
0.3
   *Closures due to RCRA costs.

   Dollar Amounts are in 1979 values.
        Table 1-5.  Results of Closure Analysis for Economic Options



1 Number of
I Shutdowns

Economic Option
1
2
3
4
5
6

Plants
3
3
3
7
7
7
Product
Lines
7
7
7
10
10
10
I Value of
I Pesticide
1 Production
1 (millions of
1 1979 dollars)
25.1
25.1
25.1
69.1
69.1
i


% of Total
Value of
Production
0.7
0.7
0.7
1.7
1.7
1.7
                                    1-12

-------
small firms bear a less than proportionate impact under economic option
1.  Only two out of 18 plants owned by small firms have costs of
compliance, none of which have a cost to sales ratio greater than  four
percent or are expected to close.  In comparison, 22 of the  62  large
plants have positive incremental costs, over one-third of  the total;  nine
of the 22 plants have cost-to-sales ratios greater than four percent; and
two plants and four product lines are predicted to close due to
incremental costs.
Impact of New Source Standards  (NSPS and PSNS)

    The potential impacts of new source treatment  standards  for  direct  and
indirect dischargers were analyzed by  assuming  that  some  new plants  would
be built.  However, projections of the  industry's  production of  fungicides
(155 million pounds), herbicides  (820  million pounds),  and  insecticides
(625 million pounds) in 1985 indicate  that little  if  any  new capacity will
be needed.

    For the impact  analysis, pesticides were grouped  into 13 subcategories
based on wastestream characteristics and treatment technologies.  A  "model"
plant was selected  for each subcategory for the purpose of  estimating  treat-
ment costs.  Treatment costs, expressed on a per pound  of pesticide  basis,
were compared with  pesticide prices.

    There is wide variability of cost  impacts among  the subcategories of
chemicals; treatment costs for direct  dischargers  range from 0 up  to 73
percent of pesticide prices.  For a comparable  chemical subcategory  and
pesticide type  (i.e., fungicide, herbicide, insecticide), treatment  cost
impacts, relative to prices, are less  for indirect dischargers than  for
direct dischargers.  In general, chemicals in subcategories  1, 6,  8, 9  and
10 show relatively  low impacts with treatment costs  no  higher than 20
percent of pesticide prices.  Of the three major types  of pesticides, new
herbicide plants generally are less severely impacted than  fungicides or
insecticides regardless of the chemical subcategory.
Limits of the Analysis
    Treatment Technologies and Costs

    The analysis relies on cost estimates  for  the  Technical Contractor  and
the use of a specific capital recovery factor, which  are  subject to  some
uncertainty.  The cost data are based on the actual characteristics  of  plants
and then in-place treatment systems.  The  cost of  capital is likely  not to
fall outside the range of 10 to 15 percent per year.
                                    1-13

-------
    Industry-Level Impacts

    The sources of possible error in the industry-level  impact  analyses
are as follows:

    1) The industry cost structure will change over time,  that  is
       the input coefficients of production inputs change; in the
       analysis, the structure is assumed to be constant out to
       1985.  Also, the forecasts of the 1985 values of  the input
       price indices are subject to error.

    2) The relation of price to cost may differ among herbicides,
       insecticides and fungicides.  The analysis uses one elas-
       ticity for all three categories.  Furthermore, the  level of
       the analysis (three major pesticide groups) is quite aggre-
       gated.  For example, no distinction is made in the price
       analyses between patented and commodity pesticide chemicals.

    3) The cost component projection and crop projections  rely  on
       DRI and U.S.D.A. models which are subject to uncertainty
       about the major variables:  acreage, fraction with pesticides
       use, and pesticide application rates.

    4) The cost-price and production price relationships were
       estimated separately but are in fact, interdependent.  This
       is not a major problem for long-run baseline forecasts,  since
       all production cost increases must eventually be passed
       through.  However, costs of compliance for existing sources
       might not be passed through completely, depending on demand
       conditions.

    5) As described above, the treatment cost estimates  used in the
       industry-level analyses have a number of uncertainties.

    6) The effect of possible significant changes in imports and
       exports is ignored in the analysis.

    7) Indirect effects on the employment, earnings, etc., of
       industries that provide inputs to the pesticide industry
       will occur, but have not been estimated in the industry-
       level analysis.

    8) Price increase assumes an average cost passthrough.
    Plant-Level Analysis;  Closure

    The criterion—annualized wastewater treatment or RCRA costs  equal to
or greater than four percent of  the value of pesticides produced  by  a
plant—was used to identify plants severely impacted.  This  criterion
would undoubtedly vary by plant  and parent company.  However, plant-
                                     1-14

-------
specific financial data are not available.  In our  judgement,  the  four
percent criterion is reasonable only as a screening device  to  be  used
together with other available information.  We also applied three,  two  and
one percent criteria to compare with the values  from  the  four  percent
screening cut off.  The results of the application of  these different
criteria on two economic options are summarized  as  follows  in  Table 1-6:
                Table 1-6.  Effect of Screening Criterion on
              Number of Plants Identified as Severely  Impacted
Treatment
Option
Economic Option 1
Economic Option 6
I Screening Criterion
1 4% 1 3%
13 15
, 30 , 32
for Cost/Sales Ratio
1 2% 1 1%
21 27
, 42 , 46
    The analysis of possible plant closures  (of  those  plants  identified  as
severely impacted) is also based on qualitative  judgements  about  each  plant
sales, production and company affiliation.  The  aggregate effect  of  plant
closures, expressed as a percent of total industry production value, is
probably a better approximation of treatment  impacts than identifying  which
specific plants are likely to shut down.  Because of uncertainty,  some plants'
compliance costs have probably been overestimated and  others  underestimated.
On balance, this should produce roughly the right number of closures,  unless
there is a significant bias to the costing procedure.

    The costs used in the RCRA closure analysis  are subject to two main
weaknesses.  First, only average costs for each  disposal method were
provided.  This overstates the impact of RCRA on small plants.  However,
this bias is probably not large because many  RCRA costs such  as management
costs are relatively fixed.  Second, RCRA costs  are probably  understated
by assuming that all of the costs of baseline treatment and storage  of
hazardous waste streams ($107 million) can be attributed to BPT rather
than RCRA regulations.  However, information  to  make an allocation between
BPT and RCRA costs was not available.
    New Source Pollution Standards

    Treatment costs are sensitive to the particular pesticide chemical
that might be produced by a new plant.  In the analysis, treatment costs
for ten model plants corresponding to ten subcategories of pesticides were
used because it is not feasible to analyze each new chemical plant that
might possibly be built.  Thus, a high and low treatment cost is  used for
                                    1-15

-------
each model plant.  For a specific model plant in a  subcategory,  the  upper
value of treatment cost may be as high as four times the low estimate  even
though the plant is described by a single value of  plant capacity.

    Prices for pesticides also vary greatly,  (even  for a given chemical
subcategory and pesticides type, i.e., fungicide or herbicide or insec-
ticides) , a high price may be as great as six times the lowest price.   The
two major uncertainties  (i.e., treatment cost and pesticide price)  are
recognized by examining the upper and lower values  of the  range  for  treat-
ment costs and for pesticides prices  in analyzing the ratio of treatment
cost to pesticide sales value.

    Treatment costs for new sources are assumed to  be the  same as those
costs that would be incurred by a major modification of an existing  plant.

    If a new plant were built to produce a patent protected pesticide
chemical, the price would be set to yield a desired profit considering all
costs of production including treatment costs.  Therefore, use of a
treatment cost to value basis on existing average values would not  be
appropriate, although the price still might fall within the broad ranges
considered in this analysis.
                                     1-16

-------
                                  Section 2
                     The  Economic Assessment Methodology
    This section describes the methodology, assumptions  and  data sources  used
in the analysis of impacts of treatment costs on  the pesticide  chemicals
industry.  The following impacts are analyzed:  prices,  production,  profit,
employment, and plant closures.  Total costs of compliance with the  proposed
effluent guidelines are also estimated.  The impacts on  the  first four  vari-
ables are estimated for the industry as a whole and for  three major  product
groups:  herbicides, insecticides, and fungicides.  Closures are predicted
for individual plants.  Part of this analysis includes determining whether
small businesses bear disproportionate impacts.   Finally, the effects of
costs for new sources on capacity expansion are analyzed.

    The main elements of the economic assessment  methodology utilize
wastewater treatment costs developed by the Technical Contractor.11   The
waste streams of each plant producing pesticide active ingredients were
studied by the Technical Contractor and one or more treatment levels (and
associated costs) that enable the plant to meet the proposed effluent
guidelines were  identified.  The plant-level analysis compares  treatment
cost estimates to sales of individual plants to identify possible plant
closures and product line shut downs.  The plant  treatment costs are also
used in the industry level analysis which analyzes  the aggregate impact of
plant costs on the pesticide chemicals industry and on the major markets
in which pesticides are used.
Industry-Level Impacts;  Price, Output, Profits,  Employment

    The industry-level analysis estimates  the  impacts of  the  proposed
effluent guidelines on three major product groups in  the  industry:
herbicides, insecticides, and fungicides,  and  on  the  industry as a whole.
Impacts are estimated for prices, production,  employment,  and profits.
The basic approach is to make a baseline forecast of  these variables  in
the absence of the proposed effluent guidelines and then  to estimate  the
changes resulting from the increase in production costs attributable  to
the guidelines.

    The methodology utilizes a cost-price  submodel and a  demand-production
submodel.  The cost-price submodel was developed  to disaggregate pesticide
prices into a profit component and several cost components.   The cost-
price submodel is used to predict the price at which pesticide  chemicals
will be supplied to users.  For the baseline,  the cost components do  not
include additional treatment costs whereas the impact projection includes
the treatment costs.

    The economic impact analysis examines  two  possible price  responses of
the industry to added treatment costs.  The first (Case A) is that the
price increase equals the average cost increase due to treatment require-
ments for all plants in the industry.  Note that  this does not  imply  that
all costs are passed through in the form of higher prices, since the
average includes those plants which do not incur  any additional costs.
The second assumption  (Case B) is that no  price increase  occurs and the

-------
industry absorbs the entire amount of treatment costs as a  reduction  in
profits.  These assumptions were selected because only a fraction  of  the
plants in the industry incur added treatment costs, making  it unlikely
that all costs can be passed through in the form of higher  prices.

    A demand-production submodel was developed to estimate  quantities of
pesticides chemicals that will be used given the two sets of projected
prices; i.e., baseline conditions and conditions with standards  imposed.
This model relates pesticide demand to its major determinants,  including
agricultural acreage, the fraction treated by pesticides, the rate  of
application, and the pesticide price.  With treatment costs included,
pesticide prices are increased under Case A which alters the demand and,
in turn, the production quantities.  The derivation of the  two  submodels
is discussed next.
    Cost-Price Submodel

    The primary focus of this study is on the active  ingredient  stage  of
the pesticide manufacturing cycle, because this stage creates  almost all
the effluent.  In 1978, the average price of pesticide  active  ingredients
was $2.34/lb. , according to the ITC-*- report.  This price  reflects  the
cost of organic chemical inputs,  inorganic chemical inputs,  fuel,
electricity, labor, overhead, and profit.

    Table 2-1 presents the 1978 price disaggregated into  its constituent
elements based on an analysis by A. D. Little.2  Inorganic chemical  inputs
account for 14.1 percent of total cost, organic chemical  inputs  for  28.2
percent, utilities for 10.6 percent, labor for 17.5 percent, and fixed costs
for 29.6 percent.  The total cost is 88.0 percent of  price or, to  put  it
differently, price is a 13.6 percent mark-up over costs.

    The disaggregation of price between costs and profits is based on  an
analysis of financial statements  of pesticide-producing companies.   The
disaggregation of costs between materials, labor, utilities, and overhead
is based on Census of Manufactures data for SIC group 28694  (pesticide
organic chemicals)3 and on publications reporting cost  breakdowns  for
the process industries.  The disaggregation of material costs  between  or-
ganic and inorganic chemical inputs is based on a review  of  pesticide
process flowcharts prepared by Parsons.4  It must be  emphasized, however,
that these disaggregations are approximations.  Using the percentage given
in Table 2-1, a pesticide cost index was developed for  the 1967-1978 period
by A. D. Little,  Inc.2  The formula for the index is:

   IPC = 0.141 IICP + 0.282 IOCP  - 0.106 IUTC - 0.175 IULC + 0.296 IFC  (1)
                                     2-2

-------
        Table 2-1.  Baseline Average Pesticide Costs  and Price,  1978
Cost Element
Inorganic Chemicals Cost
Organic Chemicals Cost
Utilities Cost
Labor Cost
Fixed Costs
Total Costs
Pre-Tax Profit
Price
1 1978
1 $/lb.*
0.29
0.58
0.22
0.36
0.61
2.06
0.28
1 2'34 1
1 Baseline Share
1 of Total Cost
14.1
28.2
10.6
17.6
29.6
100.0
13.6
113.6
   *per pound of active  ingredients.
where

     IPC  = index of pesticide costs,
     IICP = index of inorganic chemical prices,
     IOCP = index of organic  chemical prices,
     IUTC = index of utility  costs,
     IULC = index of unit  labor  costs,
     IFC  = index of fixed costs.

    Table 2-2 presents the index of pesticide  costs  for  the  1967-1978
period, along with the component cost indices  and  an index of  pesticide
active in- gredient prices.   The data in  the table were  used to fit a
regression equa- tion relating pesticide  prices  to pesticide manufacturing
costs.  The estimated equation is presented below, with  the  t-statistics
for each coefficient included in parentheses,  the  R2 and the Durbin-
Watson (DW) statistic for serial correlation:

       In IPP =  -0.647  +  1.147 In IPC                                 (2)
                (-1.483)   (13.268)


       R2 = 0.989
       DW = 1.263

       Estimation period:  1967-1978

       Estimation technique:  Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) with Cochrane-
          Orcutt correction for  autocorrelation

where
                                     2-3

-------
                                                                                               a

                                                                                                e
                 .3  =
                                                                         o

                                                                         0>
                                                                               a  f  .5
                                                                                   o  -
                U  U

                o "e
                                                                               —• —  u

                                                                                9 a  u
                                                                         C    -« w
                                                                                  o  -

                                                                               o "*  "
                                                                                  e  D
                                                                         3     o-S 2
c- -*  o
   c -<
.u O  "
C    .u
              0X00

              3 -3  L.  2
              U  C  «I
                                                                                     JJ     U  >*  •
 « —i  U  "
-*  >   •  o
   —  a  ou

f«  U   » s
    3  C
   •O  O  U
 .  0  ^  —
"  -  ^ e
3  c.  c  o
a.     —•  c
^ -3  JT  O
3  C  o  (J
O  ^  -0  1J
       I
•"  a     E
0 J   -  0

2 -
                                                                                            w  1
             C. O  C O
               £  —
                                         CM  .M •» » 3\ Q O
                                                                        O

                                                                         u
 « u  v
a  v  —
V  —4  13
                                                                        XJ     CD
                                                                              —  3O


                                                                              £1  C
                                                                                 -•  V
a jr —t
O u  >.  C.
o O =•  —
   a     u
             O'     CM
             a   .  a  O

                c  c
             O —  k.  s
             j  w  v  o
                                                                        •^    ft.  «
            •O *J  O  «  •
            c o  O  « o
                                                                                           » 3 W  01  —

                                                                                           - 5 3  "°   -

                                                                                           O     -  O  O

                                                                                              O  tr-~  Q
                                                                                           o ^-  c  c.

                                                                                                 "c  u  c
S"
0
c
o
w
*J
V
c
VI
3

a
o
w
^
fJ

3
U
^


*
3
01
^
«
3
0

•0
w
u
a
V)

2
^
~
O
3

u
•3
C
V
*J
t dnJ 1 J c I
>. u
— *
2 —
S «
CJ «

U) "
9
Q <;
ult Iply Ing the impl IcLi
t livj Of ( lea , VJa^hln'}ttv
a c

o a.
u C
-j e
~* c
3 **
u w
.^ 
-------
     IPP    =    index of pesticide prices,  and
     IPC    =    index of pesticide costs  (see Table  2-2).

    The statistics accompanying equation  (2) demonstrate  that there  is a
close relationship between prices and costs.  The  R2  is  0.989 and shows
that 98.9 percent of the variation in price  is associated with variation in
cost.  Equation  (2)  is linear  in logarithms, which implies  that the  esti-
mated coefficients can be interpreted as elasticities.  The coefficient of
the cost variable thus implies that a 10 percent rise in  pesticide costs
will cause a 11.5 percent rise in pesticide  prices.   The  finding that prices
have risen faster than costs suggests that pesticide  producers have  been
able to increase profit margins on average over the 1967-1978 period.  The
t-statistic of 13.27 indicates that the coefficient of the  cost variable is
highly significant.  However,  the standard error of the cost index coef-
ficient is too large (0.086) to reject the hypo- thesis  that the true value
of the coefficient is 1.0.Therefore, we cannot necessarily  accept the
implication that prices are rising more rapidly than  costs.*

    Equation (2) can be criticized for excluding other forces that have a
direct bearing on price.  For  example, changes in  the number of patented
products and changes in the product mix can  both affect price.  Patents
allow firms to obtain higher prices and hence profits on  such products.
Changing the product mix may change both the processes used (and hence the
input cost coefficients) and the profitability of  the products.   Because
of data limitations, a trend variable (TIME) was selected to approximate
these other forces.  The revised equation  is presented below:

       In IPP =  -0.406 + 0.989 In IPC + 0.250 In  TIME                   (3)
                (-0.750)  (4.821)         (0.854)

       R2 = 0.990
       DW = 1.369

       Estimation period:  1967-1978

       Estimation technique:   OLS with Cochrane-Orcutt

    The t-statistic  of the trend variable  indicates that  it is insignificant.
Nevertheless, it is worth examining equation (3).  The coefficient attached
to the cost variable has decreased to 0.989.  Alone,  this coefficient implies
that the pesticide producers pass the cost increases  along  to the consumer
but do not increase  profit margins.   (Since  the standard  error is .205, this
estimate is not significantly different from 1.0.)  However,  the actual re-
lationship between changes in cost and changes in  price depends on what is
imbedded in the trend variable  (TIME).
   *In addition, equation  (2) only  shows  a  relationship  of  cost  and  price
indices, not of cost shares.  Costs may increase  for a variety of  reasons
other than price increases,  including  added regulatory costs, or changes
in the mix or quality of pesticides produced.  Therefore, equation (2)  is
only a rough indicator of  profitability.
                                     2-5

-------
To the extent that costs have been increasing over time, profit  margins
may have been maintained, holding constant for product  mix.

    Equations (2) and  (3) indicate that the elasticity  of price  with respect
to cost is roughly 1.0.  An elasticity of 1.0 is  consistent  with a mark-up
model of pricing behavior:  each percentage increase  in costs  is accompanied
by the same percentage  increase in price.  Thus,  profits  as  a  percent of
costs remain constant.  Although profits may fluctuate  in the  short run due
to imbalances in supply and demand, they can be expected  to  even out over
time.  In the long-run, all costs are passed through  as higher prices,  which
is consistent with the  elasticity of price to cost of 1.0.
    1985 Price Forecasts.  Based on the above  results,  baseline  estimates
of 1985 pesticide prices are made using the assumption  that  all  costs are
passed through and that profit remains a constant  fraction of  price.   This
is because all plants  in the industry are  assumed  to  face similar  increases
in production costs.   The 1985 baseline value  of each cost component  re-
presented in equation  (1) is based on assumptions  and energy price pro-
jections issued by the U.S. Department of  Energy and  chemical  price pro-
jections by Data Resources Inc.  The cost  mark-up  model derived  from  1978
data was used to estimate baseline pesticide chemical prices in  1985.
In addition to a price for the entire industry, price forecasts  are made
for the three major groups of pesticides:  herbicides,  insecticides and
fungicides.

    As noted previously, two assumptions are made  about increases  from the
1985 baseline price due to treatment costs which reflect the fact  that only
a fraction of all plants incur added treatment costs.  In Case A,  average
treatment costs per pound  (including plants with no treatment  costs)  are
added to the baseline  price to obtain the  post-impact price.  Profit  mar-
gins are not assumed to increase proportionately;  they  remain  unchanged
from the baseline.  In Case B, prices are  not  assumed to increase. Price
increases are projected for all pesticides and for insecticides, herbi-
cides, and fungicides  for each treatment option.
    Demand-Production  Submodel

    Continuing  increases  in  the  profitability  of  pesticide application and a
growing awareness  in the  farm community of  the existence of these benefits
have  caused  a  rapid  rise  in  pesticide  demand over the  last 20 years.   There
are signs, however,  that  the industry  is  approaching maturity, with some
markets completely saturated and others not far from it.  This impending
maturity makes  it  dangerous  to forecast future pesticide demand by extrapo-
lating from  past trends,  since it is unlikely  that the industry will be able
to sustain similar high growth rates in the future.

    Unfortunately, data on pesticide usage  by  market are available only
for selected years,  thus  precluding a  disaggregated econometric analysis.
                                     2-6

-------
Consequently, a hybrid approach developed  by  A.  D.  Little,  Inc.2 was
used for forecasting pesticide demand.   First, an end-use model is used to
project pesticide demand  by  subgroup  based on constant application rates.
The end-use projections are  then  adjusted  to  reflect increases in the real
price of pesticides, using an econometrically-derived price elasticity.

    In the end-use analysis, herbicide  sales  are projected  for the
following subgroups:   (1) corn,  (2) soybeans,  (3) wheat,  (4)  cotton, (5)
sorghum,  (6) other agricultural uses,  (7)  non-agricultural  and (8) exports.

    Insecticide sales are projected for the following subgroups:
(1) cotton,  (2) corn,  (3) soybeans,  (4)  wheat,  (5)  livestock,  (6)  other
agricultural uses,  (7) non-agricultural uses,  and (8) exports.

    Fungicide sales are projected for  the  following subgroups:  (1)  fruits
and vegetables,  (2) peanuts,  (3)  other  agricultural uses, (4)  non-agri-
cultural uses, and  (5) exports.

    The approach used to  model agricultural usage of pesticides is
generally the same for each  market subgroup and  is  described  by the
following identity:
            = ACRi  x  FRACTi  X  APPLi                                      (4)


where:
           = pesticide  usage  on crop  i,
    AC%   « acreage  of crop  i  planted,
           = fraction of acreage of crop  i treated with pesticides, and
           = pesticide  usage  per acre  for crop  i.

    Various U.S. Department of  Agriculture (USDA)  publications provide
1971 and 1976 values  for the  right-hand variables  in equation (4) .   The
1985 forecasts of acreage were  obtained from the highly detailed National
Inter-Regional Agricultural Projection (NIRAP)  model maintained by  the
USDA.  Projections of the other two variables were developed by Arthur D.
Little Inc.2 pesticide  market experts.  See Section 5,  Tables 5-3 to
5-5, for the forecasts.

    Published data on non-agricultural pesticide use are not available.
Imputed values for non-agricultural use were calculated for 1971 and 1976 by
comparing the USDA survey data  on agricultural  pesticide use with data on
aggregate pesticide production,  exports,  and imports. 5, 6  (The imputed
non-agricultural values were  extremely high; USDA  officials indicated that
this was so because the agricultural  pesticide  usage numbers were under-
stated.)  The 1971 and  1976 imputed non-agricultural values are very close,
indicating a stagnating  demand  that will  persist through 1985.

    The United States has traditionally been a  large exporter of
pesticides, while imports have  been insignificant.  Trend equations were
                                     2-7

-------
used to generate initial 1985 forecasts for net exports which were  then
modified to reflect institutional factors.

    The end-use model described above implicitly assumes  that pesticide
demand is not affected by price.  Such an assumption  is unwarranted as
previous econometric research by Carlson and others has demonstrated.7
In reaction to higher real pesticide prices, farmers  are  more likely to
adopt integrated pest-management methods which are based  on  a selective
application of pesticides, along with the use of other pest  control
methods.  Also, increases in the real price of pesticides might  convince
the farmer to forego pesticide application on marginal areas and to defer
application on new areas.  Consequently, the end-use  analysis must  be
augmented to take into account the depressing effects of  real pesticide
price increases.  The augmented model is written as follows:

       PROD = EPROD -  (PE x PCPRICE x EPROD)                             (5)

where

    PROD    = U.S. production of pesticides in 1985,
    EPROD   = U.S. production of pesticides in 1985 as forecasted by the
              end-use model,
    PE      = price elasticity of demand for pesticides,  and

    PCPRICE = percentage change in real pesticide price between  1978
              and 1985.

    According to equation (5), U.S. production of pesticides in  1985 will
be less than the end-use prediction if the real pesticide price  increases
between 1978 and 1985.  The amount of this decrease will  depend  on  the
price elasticity and the percentage increase in real  price.  An
econometric estimate of the price elasticity was made using  data on
aggregate U.S. pesticide production, crop acreage, and real  active
ingredient price.

    Over the period 1967-1978, the application rate of pesticides has
increased due to the advances in technology and increases in crop prices
which made increased pesticide use profitable.  Different alternative
demand equations were estimated using a variable for  crop acreage to
capture these effects.  The following equation shows  pesticide demand as a
function of crop acreage and the real price of pesticides:

        In PRODt =  -6.109 + 2.302 In ACREt - 0.324 In RPRICEt           (6)
                    (-3.185)   (6.91)           (1.650)
                                     2-8

-------
       R2 = 0.83
       DW = 2.27

       Estimation period:  1967-1978

       Estimation technique:  OLS with Cochrane-Orcutt

where

    PROD    = pesticide production  (million  lb.),

    ACRE    = acreage of principal  crops planted,

    RPRICE  = real unit price for pesticide  active  ingredients.*
              (IPP in Table 2-2)

    Equation  (6) is linear in logarithms, which means  that  the  estimated
coefficients can be interpreted as  elasticities.  The  influence of  in-
creased insecticide use is seen in  the coefficient  of  In  ACRE.   The re-
maining effect on demand is through the price of  the pesticide.  The  co-
efficient of -0.324 for the price implies that  if real pesticide prices
rise by 10 percent, demand will decrease by  3.24 percent.

    The t-statistics, which are enclosed in  the parentheses beneath the
coefficients, indicate that there is a 90 percent probability  that  the
variables do have some impact.  The R2 value indicates that 83  percent
of the variation in pesticide production can be explained by variation in
crop acreage and pesticide price.

    Equation  (6) is relatively simple in that it  employs  a  static
formulation and was estimated by ordinary least squares (OLS) with  a
Cochrane-Orcutt correction for autocorrelation.  Such  an  approach can be
criticized for ignoring dynamics and the simultaneity  bias  problem
inherent in estimating a demand/supply system.  Equation  (7) , which
addresses both these issues, is presented below.  It contains a dynamic
Koyck lag structure and was estimated by two-stage  least  squares (TSLS)
with a Cochrane-Orcutt correction for autocorrelation:

       In PROD = -4.357 + 1.437 In  ACRE1 - 0.296  In RPRICE  +
                (-2.002) (2.459)
                0.453 In PRODt^                                         (7)

       R2 = 0.859

       DW = 2.371

       Estimation Period:  1968-1978

       Estimation Technique:  TSLS with Cochrane-Orcutt

       Instruments:  Constant, ACRE, PROD, and  IPC  (pesticide manufacture
       cost index)
   *Using the overall price index assumes that  insecticide prices  increase
at the same rate over the period 1978-85 as does the overall pesticide
price.
                                     2-9

-------
    In equation  (7)/ the short-run price elasticity  is  -0.296  and the
long-run price elasticity  is -0.541  (calculated  by dividing  -0.296 by
1-0.453).*  This implies that a 10 percent  rise  in real pesticide price
will cause a 2.96 percent  decrease in pesticide  demand  in that year,  and
if the price remains at the higher level, demand will drop another 2.45
percent in subsequent years relative to the  forecast based on  a constant
real price.

    For the projections, a price elasticity  of -0.43 was used,  which  is
the average of the elasticities from equations (6) and  (7).
    Employment

    Reliable data on employment  in  the pesticides  industry  are  not available.
Therefore, industry employment was  estimated for the  1985 baseline based on
value of shipments per employee  in  1977 for the SIC group 28694 (Pesticides
and other Organic Agricultural Chemicals, Except Preparations).  This  value
was then applied to the value of active ingredient pesticide  chemicals manu-
factured to obtain a 1977 employment estimate.  The 1985 baseline employment
estimate was then derived by applying a production ratio  (i.e. , projected
1985 production/1977 production) to the 1977 employment estimate.  The
impact of treatment options on employment was derived from  the  1985 pro-
duction impacts using the cost-price and demand-production  submodels.   That
is, the impact on employment is  baseline employment multiplied  by the
percentage output reduction.
    Profits

    For the projected baseline, industry profit  is estimated  from the  cost
mark-up model.  With regulations  imposed on the  industry,  profits are
estimated for two assumed cases.  In Case A, the dollar  profit per pound
of pesticide is the same as in the baseline and only  the costs associated
with regulations are passed along as price increases.  The impact on total
profits results from the reduction in output.  In Case B,  producers are
assumed to completely absorb  the  additional treatment cost,  i.e. , no price
increase.  In the second case, production quantities  do  not change from
the baseline level, but profit margins are more  severely affected compared
to the first case.
Plant Impact Analysis:  Closure

    The Technical Contractor estimated costs of compliance  for  each plant
in the study.  To determine whether  these costs impose  a  significant
burden on individual plants, costs of compliance  are  compared with the
value of pesticides production at each plant.  A  cutoff value of  four
   *The Koyck lag structure  implies  this  relationship  between the  annual
elasticity in equation  (7) and  the long-run elasticity.


                                     2-10

-------
percent for the ratio of treatment costs to product  value  is  used to
identify plants which may close.  All available data on  these plants,
including products produced, patents, and  relation to other company
business, are reviewed to assess whether the plant is likely  to close  as
a result of compliance costs.  In some cases, only one product line  at a
plant rather than the entire plant may shut down.

    Information developed by the Technical Contractor12  for plants
manufacturing pesticide active ingredients included  capital and annual
operating costs for different treatment levels.   The costs are expressed
as an annualized cost by converting  the capital cost to  an annualized
equivalent and adding it to the annual operating  cost.   Capital costs  are
converted to an annual equivalent by multiplying  by  a capital recovery
factor which measures the annual rate of return an investment must achieve
each year to cover the cost of the investment and maintain net earnings,
including depreciation and taxes.

    A capital recovery factor of 0.218, which was computed for the organic
chemical industry by Meta Systems Inc, was assumed to be applicable  to the
production of active pesticide ingredients.  The  capital recovery factor
is based on a 10 year life for the treatment equipment,  a  13  percent cost
of capital and five year depreciation life.  The  derivation of the capital
recovery factor is given in Appendix B.

    Information was obtained^ on the annual production of  pesticide
ingredients at each plant and on the sales value  of  that output.  The  values
of the pesticide ingredients were based on the ranges of values obtained
from the technical 308 questionnaire.  The mid-range of  product value  of the
unformulated pesticides was used in  computing a ratio of annualized  treat-
ment cost to value of sales.  The total value of  pesticide ingredients pro-
duced at each of the plants was estimated  by multiplying the  annual  produc-
tion figures and the estimated value for each active ingredient and  then
summing the results for all pesticide ingredients produced at the plant.
The total additional annualized treatment  costs were divided  by the  total
estimated value of active pesticide  ingredients at the manufacturer's  level
to obtain the ratio of treatment costs to  pesticide  ingredient value.   This
ratio was then used in an initial, screening step  of  impact severity  because
more precise plant level financial data were not  available.

    Plants with treatment costs equal to or greater  than four percent  of
pesticide value were identified for  further analysis and plants below  the
4 percent level were screened out.   The use of this  screening criterion
does not mean that plants that fall  below  the level  are  unaffected by
treatment costs.  Rather, the 4 percent criterion serves as a rough
indicator of those plants that may be severely impacted  by treatment
costs.  We have observed  (as discussed in  the Industry Profile)  that
pre-tax profit margins range between 10 and 15 percent for pesticide
producers.  Given that plants generally must make some positive return
greater than the return from immediately salvaging the plant,  a loss of
four percent in the rate of return could push a plant over the edge  of
profitability.  Some sample calculations for the  pulp and  paper  industry
                                    2-11

-------
suggest that the return from salvage might be on the order of  2  to  3
percent.*  Therefore, a plant with a 7 percent  return would  be pushed to
the shutdown point if treatment costs were 4 percent of  sales.   A plant
with a return of 7 to 10 percent would also be  in a weakened financial
condition, if it had other capital needs as well.  In addition,  a range  of
values for the cutoff ratio is considered.

    For each treatment level, the total number of severely impacted plants
was identified and the aggregate value of production determined.  The next
step was to review the available information for each plant  where treat-
ment costs exceeded four percent of sales value for any  of the treatment
levels.  (The plant level data are considered confidential and therefore
not included in this report).  Although plant level financial  data  were
not available, most of the information generally included plant  location,
types of product lines, quantities and value of pesticides and other  pro-
duct lines, period of pesticide production during the year,  parent  company
ownership and likely attitudes of firms about relocating production at
other company locations.  This type of information developed by  A.  D.
Little, Inc.2 was used in conjunction with the  treatment cost  impact  in
arriving at judgements about whether or not severely impacted  plants  (or
product lines) would be shut down.

    Plant closures are estimated both for a baseline and for the  incremental
impacts of the proposed effluent guidelines.  Costs of compliance with hazar-
dous solid waste management rules under the Resource Conservation and Recovery
Act (RCRA) are included as part of the baseline, because these rules  have
already been promulgated, but their compliance  costs have not  otherwise  been
incorporated into the data base.  Because impacts due to RCRA  may be  signifi-
cant, it is important to identify them before determining the  incremental
impacts of the proposed effluent guidelines.  Specifically,  if a  plant is
predicted to close due to RCRA costs alone, then it cannot be  counted as part
of the incremental impact of the proposed effluent guidelines, even if those
compliance costs are also high.

    Costs of compliance with RCRA requirements  were estimated  for each plant
based on various methods of disposing of process and treatment wastes.
Information was provided by the Technical Contractor about treatment  methods
used at each plant.  RCRA disposal methods were assigned to  individual
plants using a set of rules (developed in discussion with the  Technical
Contractor) that addressed on-site versus off-site disposal  capabilities as
well as disposal methods such as incineration,  deep well injection  and
landfill.  Total RCRA costs were calculated for each plant based  on the
assignment of disposal methods.

    A cutoff ratio of RCRA costs to plant product value  of four  percent  was
used to identify baseline closure candidates.   Other available information
about the plant or individual product lines was considered in  assessing
whether or not closure due to RCRA costs was likely.
   *See  "Analyzing Economic  Impacts  in  a Period of  Inflation",  EPA,  Office
of Analysis and Evaluation,  March 25, 1982, unpublished draft.
                                     2-12

-------
    In some cases, a plant will not close because of  RCRA costs  or  BAT/
PSES costs alone, but may close due to their combined effect.  These cases
are noted in Section 5.  Again, these assessments represent  best judgments
based on rather general information about each plant  and  the magnitude of
the additional costs.
    Small Business Analysis

    An analysis is conducted to determine  whether  small firms bear
disproportionate impacts under the proposed effluent  guidelines.  The method
used is to classify all firms  in  the  data  sample  as either  large  or small
and then to compare the distribution  of  impacts on plants belonging to firms
in the two sets.  The  impacts  include number  of plants  with compliance costs,
the distribution of the cost to sales ratio,  and  the  number of closures.
The analysis is primarily concerned with small firms  with limited resources
or those which would face barriers to entry due to regulation. In  light  of
these considerations,  we have  defined small businesses  to be those  having
less than $10 million  in annual sales.   18 out of  the 80 plants in  the data
base, 23 percent of the total, fall under  this definition of a small
business.
New Source Standards

    Treatment costs were estimated  by  the  Technical Contractor  for  new
plants, considering both direct  and indirect  dischargers.13'14   Types of
treatment subcategories were  then postulated  to  handle different waste
streams that might be generated  by  new plants.   Model plant sizes were
identified by the Technical Contractor for each  subcategory.  The treat-
ment costs are considered  high because the estimates are  for  "end-of-pipe"
treatment whereas a new plant design would be likely to utilize in-plant
waste stream controls to reduce  total  plant costs.   However,  no data are
available to estimate the  degree by which  "end-of-pipe" treatment costs
may be overestimated when  these  costs  are  used for  analyzing  new sources.

    The major groups of pesticides—i.e.,  fungicide,  herbicide  and
insecticide—that might be produced by a plant in each subcategory  were
identified and price ranges for  the pesticides were determined  to estimate
ranges of product values for  the model plants considered.12,13/14

    As in the plant-level  analysis, impacts are  assessed  primarily  based
on the ratio of annualized treatment costs (annualized capital  costs plus
O&M costs) to the plant's  product value.

    The likehood that new  pesticide chemicals manufacturing plants  will be
built by 1985 is assessed.  This assessment is based on existing plant
capacities for producing the  three  major groups   of pesticides  and  the
demands for those products by 1985  as  projected  by  Arthur  D.  Little Inc.
and by Frost and Sullivan.15
                                     2-13

-------
                                  Section 3

                              Industry Profile
    The pesticide industry is a two-tiered business encompassing  at  one
level, producers of. pesticide chemicals  (active ingredients) and  at  the
second level, formulators who combine the active  ingredients with sub-
stances such as diluents, emulsifiers and wetting agents so that  the
pesticides can be applied by the ultimate users.  Many of  the  firms  making
the active chemical ingredients are also formulators, however,  there are
also numerous independent formulators.

    Pesticide active ingredients are primarily synthetic organic  chemicals
that are covered in SIC  28694  (Pesticide and Other Organic Agricultural
Chemicals, Except Preparation) which is part of SIC 2869,  (Industrial
Organic Chemicals N.E.C.  (not elsewhwere classified)).  The forraulators
and packagers of pesticide products are classfied in SIC 2879,  (Pesticides
and Agricultural Chemical Producers, N.E.C.).

    As of January 1979,  there were 7,875 pesticide producers or formulating
plants according to the  Establishment Registration System  of the  EPA.  EPA
has determined that formulators operate essentially as a "zero discharge"
industry with only minor volumes of aqueous wastestreams.  Furthermore, many
of the formulating plants may carry out no actual formulating  or  manufacturing
operations but are only  involved in handling the  formulated products.

    According to the 1977 Census of Manufacturers, there were  only 420
establishments whose primary business was classified in SIC 2879,  the SIC
group that includes pesticide formulators and, according to EPA and
Technical Contractor data, there are only 117 plants in the U.S.  that make
pesticide chemical active ingredients.

    U.S. pesticide manufacturers produced 1.5 billion pounds of pesticide
active ingredient chemicals in 1980 valued at about $4.3 billion.  These
ingredients were formulated with various inert materials and then distri-
buted to agricultural and other users.  Table 3-1 gives historical produc-
tion, value, and pricing data on the domestic pesticide chemicals
manufacturing industry.
Structure of Demand

    The most common categorization of pesticides  is  by  type of pest
controlled:  weeds, insects, fungal diseases, and the like.  In the
agricultural sector (which constitutes the major market for pesticide
products) it is estimated that, for every $1 spent on pesticides, the
fanner obtains, on the average $5 in increased yields as a result of
lower crop losses.16  Three classes of products—herbicides, insecti-
cides, and fungicides—compose virtually all domestic pesticide produc-
tion, although small amounts of rodent and bird-control materials are
also produced.  In simple terms, herbicides are used to eliminate weeds,
fungicides are used to protect plants from fungus, and  insecticides are
used to kill insects.

-------
          Table  3-1.  Total U.S..  Pesticide  Chemicals Production1
                                 (1967-1978)
1 Production !
1 Million I
Year I Pounds 1
1967 1,050
1968 1,192
1969 1,104
1970 1,034
1971 1,136
1972 1,157
1973 1,289
1974 1,417
1975 1,603
1976 1,364
1977 1,388
1978 1,417
1979 1,429
1980 1,468
Average Annual Growth
1967-1974 4.4
1974-1980 0.6
1 1
Value2 !
Million $ I
Current 1
987
1,137
1,113
1,074
1,248
1,295
1,449
1,958
2,871
2,768
3,119
3,289
3,706
4,281
(%)
10.3
13.9
1
Constant4 I
987
1,120
1,039
961
1,116
1,127
1,206
1,336
1,382
1,277
1,304
1,322
1,336
1,380

4.4
0.5
1 Average Price^
$/lb
Current 1
0.94
0.95
1.01
1.04
1.10
1.12
1.12
1.38
1.79
2.03
2.25
2.32
2.59
2.92

5.6
13.3
1 1
Constant5
0.94
0.91
0.92
0.90
0.90
0.88
0.84
0.95
1.13
1.21
1.27
1.22
1.26
1.30

0.1
5.4

    Herbicides, insecticides, and fungicides.
   2
    Value is the sum of the value columns in Tables 3-3,  3-4,  and  3-5.

    Average price is value/total production.
   4
    Constant dollars for pesticide values are calculated  using  pesticide
price indices shown in Table 2-2  (1967=100).

    Constant dollars for pesticide average  prices  are  calculated using  a
GNP Deflator (1967=100).
   Source:  U.S. International Trade Commission, Arthur D.  Little,  Inc.,
and Meta Systems Inc calculations.
                                     3-2

-------
    Production of herbicides, insecticides, and fungicides has changed
considerably over the past two decades.  Figure 3-1 demonstrates  the
changes in production of these products.  Herbicides have taken the lead
in production only since 1975.  The  sharp decline  in herbicide production
in 1969 was due to a disruption in the supply of the intermediate  chemi-
cals used in manufacturing herbicides.  This disruption was caused by an
increase in demand for defoliants during the Vietnam War from which the
industry took several years to recover.  Insecticide production has been
increasing since 1976 when it fell off by almost 100 million pounds.
Fungicide production has stayed about the same over the past ten  years.

    Herbicides constitute the newest and most important group of  pesticides.
Table 3-2 shows that herbicides accounted for about 60 percent of  the total
value of pesticide chemical production in 1977 and 49 percent of  the total
quantity of pesticides produced.  The relative contribution of each product
class to total production of pesticide is also shown in Table 3-2,

    Historical data on production and dollar value of herbicides,
insecticides, and fungicides, are presented in Tables 3-3, 3-4, and 3-5,
respectively.  The tables demonstrate that all of  the pesticide groups
have experienced considerable growth since 1967.

    Herbicide production has grown most dramatically, increasing  from 409
million pounds in 1967 to 805 million pounds in 1980, which is an  average
annual growth rate of 5.3 percent.  The major agricultural markets for
herbicides are corn, soybeans, wheat, and cotton.1?  Corn is particularly
important, accounting for about half the agricultural herbicide market.
The non-agricultural herbicides are used on lawns, parks, and golf courses,
and in the control of vegetation along right-of-way areas.

    Insecticides kill by contact with, or ingestion by, the insect.
Insecticides can be aimed at a specific major pest, such as the boll
weevil, or at a broad spectrum of insects.  The major agricultural markets
for insecticides are cotton, corn, peanuts, fruits and vegetables, with
cotton accounting for about one-third the 1976 agricultural applications.
Insecticides are also used by livestock farmers and in a variety  of
non-agricultural applications.

    The 496 million pounds of insecticides produced in 1967 represented 90
million pounds more than the herbicide volume for  that year, but  by 1980,
insecticide production of 506 million pounds was 300 million pounds less than
that of herbicides.  Thus, insecticides may be considered a relatively mature
market; their 1967-1980 average annual growth rate of less than one percent
is significantly lower than that of herbicides.

    Fungicides represent a relatively minor group  of pesticides.   In 1980,
production of 156 million pounds of fungicides represented only about 10
percent of total pesticide production and even less of pesticide  value.
Furthermore, the fungicide market is stagnant, with the 1978 production
                                     3-3

-------
Figure 3-1.  Annual Pesticide Production by Product Type
   900
   800
   700
   SOO
   900
   400
   300
   200
    100
      SO   52   54   S3   S3   70   72
       Source:  Arthur D. Little
                          3-4

-------
             Table 3-2.   Estimated Composition of U.S. Pesticide
                        Chemicals Production  in  1977
                                (1977 Dollars)
! Production

Class
Herbicides
Insecti-
cides
Fungicides
Totals
1 Million
1 libs.
674

570
143
1 *"™ 1
1
1 Percent
49

41
10
100
1 Valuel | Average Unit Value
1 Million
1 S
1,867

1,049
203
1 3,119
1 1
1 Percent 1
60

34
6
1 10° 1

$/lb
2.77

1.84
1.42

    Represents the value of active ingredients produced.
   Source:  U.S. International Trade Commission, calculations by Meta  Systems
Inc.
level 33 million pounds less than that of 1960.  Most  fungicides  are
contact products and are used as a preventative measure.  The plant is
coated with the fungicide which protects it from disease.  A new  type of
fungicide—and one that offers growth potential to the  industry—is the
systemic fungicide.  These products, unlike the contact group, can
actually reverse disease therapeutically.

    The major agricultural markets for fungicides are  fruits and
vegetables, particularly citrus fruits; peanut and cotton fanners are also
important users.  Non-agricultural uses of fungicide are also significant,
with the applicaton of pentachlorophenol as a wood preservative for poles
and posts being the most important.
Structure of Supply
    Producers of Pesticide Chemicals

    There are difficulties in characterizing the suppliers of pesticides
because there are few companies for which pesticides are considered a
major source of revenue.  There are no publicly-owned companies  in which
pesticides are considered the prime source of revenue.  In 1977,  81 com-
panies reported the manufacture of pesticide active ingredients  to the
U.S. International Trade Commission  (ITC).  These producers included
petroleum companies  (e.g., Shell), chemical companies  (e.g., Dow and
DuPont), and pharmaceutical-based firms  (e.g., Eli Lilly and Pfizer).
                                     3-5

-------
               Table  3-3.   U.S.  Herbicide  Production  (1967-1980)
1
1
Year 1
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
Average Annual
1967-1974
1974-1980 ,
Production
Million
Pounds
409
469
393
404
429
451
496
604
788
656
674
664
658
805
Growth (%)
5.7
4.9
1
1 Value2
1 Million $
617
718
662
663
781
812
843
1,214
1,781
1,692
1,867
1,843
2,020
2,695

10.1
14.2
1 Average Pricel
I
I $/lb
1.51
1.53
1.68
1.64
1.82
1.80
1.70
2.02
2.26
2.58
2.77
2.78
3.07
3.35

4.2
. 8.8
    Average price is the quantity weighted average price of cyclic  and
acrylic herbicide merchant shipments in current dollars.
   2
    Value is derived as weighted average price x production volume.

   Sources:  U.S. Tarriff Commission (to 1973), U.S. International  Trade
Commission  (1974-1977), and Arthur D. Little, Inc., calculations.
                                     3-6

-------
             Table  3-4.   U.S.  Insecticide Production (1967-1980;
                  Production
Year
Million
Pounds
 Value2
Million $
                                     Average  Price^-
$/lb
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
 496
 569
 571
 490
 558
 564
 639
 650
 659
 566
 570
 606
 617
 506
Average Annual Growth  (%)
1967-1974              3.9
1974-1980             -4.0
    304
    347
    383
    340
    385
    344
    492
    605
    916
    911
  1,049
  1,232
  1,407
  1,279
                        10.3
                        13.3
0.
0.
0.61
0.61
 .67
 .69
0.69
0.61
0.77
0.93
 .39
 ,61
 .84
 .03
 .28
1.
1.
1.
2.
2.
2.56
                      6.2
                     18.4
    Average price is the quantity weighted  average  price  of  cyclic  and
acrylic insecticide merchant shipments  in current dollars.

    Value is derived as weighted average price  x production  volume.
   Sources:  U.S. Tarriff Commission and Arthur D.  Little, Inc.,  estimates.
                                     3-7

-------
              Table  3-5.   U.S.  Fungicide  Production (1967-1980)
1
1
Year 1
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
Average Annual
1967-1974
1974-1980
Production
Million
Pounds
144
154
141
140
149
143
154
163
155
142
143
147
155
156
Growth (%)
1.8
-0.7
1 1
1 Value2 I
1 Million $ 1
66
72
68
71
82
93
114
139
174
165
203
214
279
307

11.2
14.1
Average Price^
$/lb
0.46
0.47
0.48
0.51
0.55
0.65
0.74
0.85
1.12
1.16
1.42
1.46
1.80
1.97

9.2
15.0
    Average price is the quantity weighted average price of cyclic  and

acrylic fungicides merchant shipments.

   2
    Value is calculated as weighted average price x production  volume.


   Sources:  U.S. Tarriff Commission and Arthur D. Little,  Inc.,  estimates.
                                     3-8

-------
    The production of basic chemicals is  the first  and most  complex  phase
of the pesticides industry.  It  involves  the synthesizing  of technical-
grade chemicals from raw materials.  There are twenty major  classes  of  raw
materials and chemical intermediates used in the manufacture of  pesticides,
and in recent years about 2.5 billion pounds of these raw  materials,  valued
at over $1.6 billion, are consumed  annually by the  pesticide industry.
Table 3-6 lists the major chemical  groups and raw materials  that are used
in manufacturing pesticides.  It also shows the proportional contribution
that each group makes to the total  estimated value  of pesticide  production.

    Pesticides are generally manufactured in plants which  also produce  other
organic chemicals, including Pharmaceuticals, plastics,  and  resins.
Approximately 95 percent of the  plants produce no more than  four pesticides,
while almost 50 percent produce only one.  The pesticides, with  the  excep-
tion of such high-volume products as the  cotton insecticide, toxaphene,  are
not generally produced throughout the year.  The plants  in the industry also
vary widely in size.  The outputs of a number of plants  are  worth more  than
$75 million, and 12 of the 117 manufacturing plants account  for  slightly
more than 50 percent of the total value of the outputs.  In  contrast, almost
half of the plants have an annual market  value for  all pesticide chemicals
of less than $5 million.

    Table 3-7 lists production, value, and market share  data for the top 18
pesticide producers.  The top four  companies account for about half  of  the
industry's market share by value and the  top eight  firms account for 82
percent of the market share.  Different segments of the  pesticide industry,
however,  exhibit varying degrees of concentration; for  example, the top
four producers of corn insecticides account for 81  percent of the market
share and the top four soybean insecticide producers have  77 percent of the
market.  Thus, within the various pesticide segments there are high  levels
of industrial concentration.
    Profile of Pesticide Chemicals Plants

    The EPA identified 117 separate plants  (belonging  to  81  companies)
that produced pesticide chemicals in 1977.  All 117 plants produce  pesti-
cide active ingredients, and 55 of the 117  also formulate and package  the
pesticide products.  Thus about half the manufacturing plants are verti-
cally integrated operations.  While all the 117 plants produce  pesticide
chemicals, this is not necessarily their sole line of  business,  nor is  it
necessarily a business that they carry on continually.  About three-
quarters of the plants (87) produce various chemicals other  than
pesticides.

    Table 3-8 shows a classification of the 117 manufacturing plants by
major type of pesticides produced:  herbicides, insecticides, fungicides,
and mixed pesticide products.  In classifying the plants, for purposes  of
the impact analysis, the fact that almost three-quarters of  them also
                                     3-9

-------
                 Table 3-6.  Raw Materials and Key Chemical
                 Intermediates  Used  in  Pesticide  Manufacture
Product Group
Percent of Total
 Estimated Value
  of Production
Phenol and derivatives

Aniline derivatives

Cyanide derivatives

Carboxylic acid derivatives

Higher alkyl amines

Phosphorous pentasulfide

Benzene and related compounds

Phosgene

Chlorine

Phosphorous trichloride

Mercaptans

Bromine

Monomethylamine

Aldehydes

Carbon disulfide

L-Pinene

Cyclodienes



    Total
       25.3

       12.4

       12.3

       11.3

        8.5

        5.5

        4.9

        4.2

        3.7

        3.2

        3.0

        2.6

        1.2

        1.1

        0.4

        0.4
      100.0%
   Source:  U.S. Pesticides Market; Report IA907, Frost  & Sullivan,  Inc.,
New York, New York, May 1981.
                                     3-10

-------
             Table 3-7.  Pesticide Market by Producer, 1980
                              (1980 Dollars)
1
1
Company 1
Monsanto
Ciba-Geigy
Stauffer
Eli Lilly
DuPont
Cyanamid
Union Carbide
Shell
FMC
Mo bay
BASF-Wyandotte
Diamond-Shamrock
Rohm & Haas
Uniroyal
Velsicol
1C I
01 in
Standard Oil
(Calif)
Total .2,
1
Value |
($MM) i
522-580
354-358
330
285-300
220
220
150-160
132-155
135-140
125-135
75-100
75
41-46
36
18
10-20
10-15

5
773-2,913,
Production
(MM Ibs. ) 1
169-173
142-147
105-117
72-82
75-99
82
57-73
40-55
55
40-45
20-25
25-30
13-15
11
9-10
—
5

2-3
1
1 % Market
1 Share by
! Value
20
13
12
10
8
8
6
5
5
5
3
3
1
1
—
—
—

—
100
1
1 % Cummulative
1 Market Share
20
33
45
55
63
71
77
82
87
92
95
98
99
100
—
—
—

—
1

Source:  U.S. Pesticides Market; Frost & Sullivan
                                 3-11

-------
                                 Table 3-8
              Profile of Pesticide Plants — Subcategorization


Subcategory                                Number of Plants

Herbicides
  An Hides-cyclic                                 3
  Triazines-cyclic                                2
  Hydrazides-cyclic                               3
  Benzoics-cyclic                                 3
  Phenoxies-cyclic                                4
  Dinitrophenols and anilines-cyclic              1
  Ureas-cyclic                                    1
  Miscellaneous                         '        	7_

      Total                                      24
Insecticides
  Aldrin-toxaphene-cyclic                         3
  Organophosphorus-cyclic                         3
  Carbamates-cyclic                               2
  Chloro-organic-cyclic                           3
  Nematocides-cyclic                              1
  Rodenticides-cyclic                             2
  Attractants and repellants-cyclic               2
  Synergists-cyclic                               2
  Organophosphorus-acyclic                        4
  Miscellaneous                                  19

      Total                                      41
Fungicides
  Polychloro-aromatics-cyclic                     4
  Chloroalkyl amides                              1
  Miscellaneous                                 	8

      Total                                      13

Mixed* Total                                     39

Total                                           117
   *Production of pesticides is in more than one subcategory.
                                    3-12

-------
manufacture non-pesticide products is not considered.  Thus/ subcategor-
ization and the associated discussion relate exclusively  to  the  pesticide
operations of the plants.  Twenty-four plants mainly produce herbicides,
and their average production value is twice that of insecticide  producers
and nine times that of fungicide producers.

    Forty-one plants are classified as insecticide producers/  13 as
fungicide producers/ and the remaining 39 plants manufacture more  than  one
type of product.  The mixed-product plants tend to be  larger than  the
single-product plants; their average production value  is  almost  twice that
of the herbicide producers.

    The first three groupings can be further subdivided by the types of
chemicals produced.  Thus herbicides can be subdivided into  anilides,
triazines, hydrazides, benzoics/ phenoxies/ dinitrophenols/anilines,
ureas, and miscellaneous.  The major herbicides in the anilide group are
alachlor and propachol.  The former is used extensively on soybeans and
corn, the latter on sorghum.  The most important herbicide in  the
triazines group is atrazine, which dominates the corn  market.  The phen-
oxies group includes 2, 4-D, the use of which has come under environmental
restriction.

    Insecticides are subdivided into aldrin-toxaphene, cyclic  organophosphorus,
acyclic organophosphorus, carbamates, chloro-organics, nematocides,
rodenticides, attractants/repellants, synergists, and  miscellaneous.
Acyclic organophosphorus is the most important group,  and the  insecticides
in this group have a wide range of applications, particularly  in  corn  and
livestock.  The cyclic organophosphorus group includes methyl  parathion,
which is used on wheat and corn.  Insecticides in the  aldrin-toxaphene
group are used in cotton, soybeans, and livestock.  The fungicides are
subdivided into polychloro-aromatics, chloroalkyl amides, and  miscellaneous.
    Capacity Utilization.  The pesticides manufacturing  industry overall
operated at a capacity utilization rate of  80 percent  in 1979.  Thus,
while 1,429 million pounds of pesticide chemicals were produced in  1979,
capacity was available to produce about 1,800 million  pounds.  The  compo-
nents of the industry  (fungicides/ insecticides, herbicides)  varied with
respect to utilization of available capacity and Table 3-9  lists production
capacity and capacity utilization in 1979.
    Formulators

    It is difficult to describe pesticide formulators because  there  are  a
large number of small operators for which statistical information  is not
available.  As mentioned earlier, while almost 8,000 plants were counted
as formulators in 1979, in fact, many of these are distributors of
formulated products.
                                    3-13

-------
                                  Table  3-9
            Pesticide  Production  and Capacity  Utilization in 1979
Type of |
Pesticide 1
Fungicides
Herbicides
Insecticides
All pesticides
Production
(million Ibs.
155
657
617
1,429
I Capacity
1 (million Ibs. )
184
888
726
1,786
1 Capacity I
1 Utilization I
.84
.74
.85
.80
   Source:   U.S. Pesticide Market, Frost & Sullivan  (capacity  values
calculated by Meta Systems Inc.
    Technical grade pesticide chemicals are rarely used  in  the pure  form
manufactured by the chemical firms but are mixed with inert materials  in
the formulation stage.  Mixing serves the dual purpose of stabilizing  the
chemicals and preparing them in a form that will be useful  to end users.
The form into which the chemicals are formulated depends upon such  factors
as the type of pest being controlled, the environment, the desired method
of application and the properties of the technical grade chemical.   Pesti-
cides are produced as dry or liquid concentrates and are then generally
formulated to meet application requirements.  Dry concentrates include
dusts, granules, and wettable powders.  Liquid concentrates consist  of
solutions and stable suspensions.

    New systems are being developed for the application  of  pesticides, the
most current being micro-encapsulation, or controlled release.   This pro-
cess is still unproven on a large scale and is quite expensive,  but  its
developers  (Health-Chem and Penwalt) claim it has superior  field life  and
efficiency.

    Prior to 1970, the formulation of technical-grade pesticides was carried
out by a variety of independent firms and agricultural cooperatives.  Formu-
lating firms bought pesticides from the basic manufacturers and  formulated
and packaged the products for sale.  In the mid-1970's there was an  overall
domestic shortage of chemicals and during this period many  of the technical-
grade pesticide producers integrated forward and formulated their own
chemicals captively.  Although the chemical shortage is  now over, most of
the chemical manufacturers have chosen to stay in the formulating business.
The current estimate in the Kline Guide is that  80 percent  of the formulated
pesticide industry is controlled by technical-grade producers.
                                     3-14

-------
Profitability

    As mentioned earlier, most of the U.S. pesticide production  is  carried
on by diversified companies and their sales of pesticides  are a  minor
source of the firms' revenue.  Therefore,  the availability of reliable
financial data on pesticide production is  extremely limited.  Investment
analysts regard pesticide production as a  very profitable  business  with
profit margins much higher than is suggested by an analysis of income
statements.  For example, one investment house  (Loeb Rhodes and  Company)
estimates that the average net margin in sales  (after  taxes and  all
charges) exceeds 20 percent.  However, a detailed examination of the
annual reports and 10-K statements of pesticide producers  revealed  that
line-of-business, pre-tax profit margins in 1978 typically range between
10 and 15 percent.  This finding is consistent with the  Federal  Trade
Commission's statement that chemical industry pre-tax  profit margins  in
1978 averaged 10.6 percent  (versus 8.0 percent  for all manufacturing).18
    There are many individual pesticide products on which  profit  margins
exceed 40 percent.  These are the proprietary  (patented) products for
which the absence of competition allows the patent-holder  to price  the
product considerably higher than cost.  The life of a  patent  is  17  years
and pesticide manufacturers aggressively seek  to develop new pesticides to
maintain their pool of patented products.  The National Agricultural
Chemical Association reported that pesticide research  and  development
expenditures in 1978 accounted for 8 percent of sales  revenue.  Neverthe-
less, in 1978, only 3 new pesticides were  registered versus 28
registrations in 1966.19

    The slowdown in the rate of new pesticide  introduction is attributable,
in part, to governmental regulation, which has increased both the time and
cost required to commercialize a new pesticide.  The regulation of  pesti-
cides dates back to 1910, but it was only  in 1947  that the Federal
Insecticide, Fungicide, and Rodenticide Act  (FIFRA), as administered by
the USDA, required pesticides to be federally  registered.   The Federal
Environmental Pesticide Control Act  (FEPCA) of 1972 and the Federal
Pesticide Act of 1978, as administered by  the  EPA, define  the current
requirements for federal registration.
Research and Development

    Research and development plays  a major  role  in the  continued  success
of chemical producers.  Because of  the cost and  time  required  to  develop
new pesticides, R&D  activities are  concentrated  in about  30  companies.
These are, generally, large, multi-product  companies  which can afford
risky ventures.  Thus, to  the extent that pesticide operations are  very
profitable, examples of such profitability  are likely to  be  found among
the large companies.
                                     3-15

-------
    The amount of money invested annually on pesticide R&D increased from
$61 million in 1967 to $290 million in 1978 (in current dollars) ,15
This is due in part to the increased complexity of pesticide chemicals and
new prohibitions on broad spectrum pesticides, but testing and  regulatory
requirements also play a major role in added R&D expenditures.   The 1978
Amendments to the Federal Insecticide, Fungicide and Rodenticide Act  (FIFRA)
are estimated by Frost and Sullivan to add 33 percent to the cost of regis-
tering a new pesticide and over 50 percent to the costs of re-registration.15

    On the average, the entire process of developing and testing a new
pesticide takes six to eight years and costs about $15 million.  In 1978 only
three new pesticides were registered, compared to 1966, when 28 new pesti-
cides were introduced, with an average development time of four years and a
cost of $2 million.  R&D costs in the pesticide industry are expected to
increase.20/21  The likely consequence of such an increase will be further
concentration of the industry with only the largest firms either willing or
able to afford the high R&D costs.  High R&D costs and the uncertainty
inherent in the commercialization of a new pesticide pose major barriers to
new firms seeking to enter the industry.  The successful companies in the
future are likely to be those with existing technical bases  (e.g.,
pharmaceutical companies) and/or those with long-term positions in the
industry.
Imports and Exports

    The U.S.  is a net exporter of pesticides and  in  1977  exports  exceeded
imports by 263 million pounds.  Tables 3-10 through  3-12  present  data on
production, exports and  imports of pesticide products  for 1966  to 1977.
As shown in Table 3-10,  in 1977, the United States exported  109.4 million
pounds of herbicides which amounted to 16 percent of domestic production.
The 1977 export figures  represent an increase of  87  million  pounds since
1966.  Imports of herbicides equalled 15.9 million pounds or 2.3  percent
of total domestic production.

    Insecticide exports  (Table 3-11) were 146.3 million pounds  or 25.7
percent of total production, in 1977, and imports represented  .12 percent
of domestic production.  Exports of herbicides  (Table  3-12)  for the same
year were 27.1 million pounds and accounted for 19 percent of domestic
production, while imports were 2.5 million pounds or 1.7  percent  of total
production.

    Table 3-13 presents  annual growth rates for both volume  and value of
exports for the three major pesticide classes.  From 1969 to 1977 the
volume of herbicide exports grew by 15 percent  annually while  the value  of
those exports grew 22 percent a year.  The volume of insecticides exported
grew 1.7 percent per year and the dollar value  of those exports grew in
value by 15 percent a year.  Fungicide exports  grew  5  percent  a year and
the value of  fungicide exports grew 20 percent  ayear between 1969 and 1977.
                                     3-16

-------
            Table 3-10.  U.S. Production and Trade  in Herbicides
Year I
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1
Production
(MM Ib)
324
409
469
393
404
429
451
496
604
788
656
674
1
1 Exports |
1 (MM Ib) 1
22.5
32.4
37.0
34.8
39.0
42.3
—
80.6
106.1
106.7
104.2
109.4
1 1
Exports as a
Percent of
Production
6.9
8.0
8.1
8.9
9.7
9.9
—
16.3
17.6
13.5
15.9
16.0
1 1 Imports as a
1 Imports 1 Percent of
1 (MM Ib) | Production
1.1
2.7
3.0
2.3
2.4
5.7
4.4
7.6
9.2
12.2
13.1
15.9
1 1
0.3
0.7
0.6
0.6
0.6
1.0
1.3
1.5
1.5
1.6
2.0
2.3
Sources:
   Production is from International Trade Commission, Synthetic  Organic
Chemicals  (Washington, D.C., U.S. Government Printing Office) various
issues.

   Imports and exports are converted to an active  ingredient basis  by
halving the values as reported in U.S. Department  of Agriculture, The
Pesticide Review (Washington, D.C., U.S. Department of Agriculture,
Agricultural Stabilization and Conservation Service).
                                    3-17

-------
           Table 3-11.  U.S. Production and Trade in Insecticides
Year 1
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1
Production
(MM Ib)
552
496
569
571
490
558
564
639
650
659
566
570
1
1 Exports 1
1 (MM Ib) 1
131.0
140.2
161.3
128.1
118.2
118.8
—
208.7
212.2
178.5
148.2
146.3
1 1
Exports as a
Percent of
Production
23.7
28.3
28.3
22.4
24.1
21.3
—
32.7
32.7
27.1
26.2
25.7
1 1 Imports as a
1 Imports | Percent of
1 (MM Ib) I Production
0.3
0.2
0.09
0.4
0.3
0.4
2.3
1.7
0.9
0.7
0.7
0.7
1 1
.05
.04
.02
.07
.06
.07
.40
.30
.14
.01
.12
.12
Sources:
   Production is from International Trade Commission, Synthetic Organic
Chemicals  (Washington, D.C., U.S. Government Printing Office) various
issues.

   Imports and exports are converted to an active ingredient basis  by
halving the values as reported in U.S. Department of Agriculture, The
Pesticide Review (Washington, D.C., U.S. Department of Agriculture,
Agricultural Stabilization and Conservation Service).
                                    3-18

-------
            Table 3-12.  U.S. Production and Trade  in Fungicides
Year 1
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1
Production
(MM Ib)
137
144
154
141
140
149
143
154
163
155
142
143
1
I Exports !
I (MM Ib) |
21.2
19.2
18.8
18.1
20.6
21.5
21.0
29.2
30.0
23.9
25.2
27.1
1 !
Exports as a I
Percent of 1
Production I
15.5
13.3
12.2
12.8
14.7
14.4
14.7
19.0
18.4
15.4
17.7
18.9
1
1 Imports as a
Imports | Percent of
(MM Ib) | Production
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.2
0.6
1.4
2.7
2.0
1.2
2.4
2.3
2.5
1
0.1
0.1
0.2
0.1
0.4
0.9
1.9
1.3
0.7
1.5
1.6
1.7
Sources:
   Production is from International Trade Commission,  Synthetic  Organic
Chemicals  (Washington, D.C., U.S. Government Printing  Office) various
issues.

   Imports and exports are converted to an active  ingredient basis  by
halving the values as reported in U.S. Department  of Agriculture, The
Pesticide Review (Washington, D.C., U.S. Department of Agriculture,
Agricultural Stabilization and Conservation Service).
                                    3-19

-------
               Table  3-13.   Annual  Growth  Rates  for  Volume  and
                   Value of Pesticide Exports (1969-1977)
Product Class     I       Production  (%)      I         Value *  (%)
Herbicides
Insecticide
Fungicide
15
1.7
5 1
22
15
20
   * in current dollars.

   Source:  U.S. Pesticides Market, Frost & Sullivan.
    Of the 49 million pounds of pesticides imported by the United States
in 1977, West Germany was the originator of 31 percent, the United Kingdom
of 29 percent and Japan of 10 percent.
Industry Outlook

    Market forecasts for pesticide sales are complicated by the  industry's
dependence on such different variables as weather, farm income,  predicted
insect infestations, previous years' pesticide inventory, and changing
health and environmental regulations.  Regardless of the uncertainties  in
predicting changes in the production and value of pesticides, however,  the
use of pesticides can be expected to grow.  In the United States alone,
the application of pesticides has increased at an average rate of  3.4 per-
cent a year or about 40 percent over the past decade.  It is reasonable to
expect a general trend of modest growth to continue over the next  five
years.

    Production of pesticides was 1.4 billion pounds in 1980 and  is
expected to grow about 1.4 percent annually until 1985 when production  is
anticipated to reach 1.5 billion pounds according to one source  (Frost  and
SullivanlS).  The dollar value of this production is projected to  in-
crease by 8.4 percent a year from $4.3 billion in 1980 to $6,4 billion  in
1985, expressed in current dollars.  According to another source,22  the
average annual rate of growth in value of pesticide production,  expressed
in constant dollars, is projected at 5.0 percent between 1980 and  1985.

    The three major product classes that make up the pesticide industry
are expected to grow at different rates during the 1980-1985 period, with
herbicides growing at the highest rate  (in terms of both volume  and  value)
and insecticides growing at the lowest annual rate.  Table  3-14  shows  the
projected annual growth rates for the pesticide market by product  class.
                                    3-20

-------
    The structure of the pesticides industry is not expected  to  change
markedly in the next five years.  Increasing research  and  development
costs and rising raw materials prices can be expected  to result  in  the
exclusion of small companies from competition/ but the top ten companies
are likely to maintain their market shares relative to one another.
                Table 3-14.  Pesticide Market by Major Class—
                      Yearly Rate of Growth (1980-1985)
Product Class      I      Production  (%)       I        Value*  (%)
Herbicides
Insecticide
Fung icide
Total Industry
1.9
0.9
1.4
1.4 ,
8.6
7.8
8.4
8.4
   * In current dollars.
   Source:  U.S. Pesticide Market, Frost & Sullivan.
                                    3-21

-------
                                  Section 4
                   Recommended Treatment Technologies and
                              Associated Costs
    The 1972 Federal Water Pollution Control Act  (FWPCA) amendments  (Public
Law 92-0500) were primarily directed at the control of  industrial  and muni-
cipal wastewater discharges.  The legislation and subsequent amendments
(Clean Water Act of 1977, Public Law 95-217) require  that EPA  revise and
promulgate effluent limitations and standards for all point sources of
pollution.  Under FWPCA amendments, EPA must develop  technology-based
effluent limitations for conventional pollutants  (Section 301).  Under
another part of the legislation  (Section 307) , EPA must develop effluent
standards for individual toxic chemicals and pretreatment standards for
indirect industrial discharges to publicly owned  treatment works.  These
permissible levels of pollutant discharge correspond  to Best Practicable
Control Technology Currently Available  (BPT) and  Best Available Technology
Economically Achievable  (BAT) and Pretreatment Standards for Existing
Sources (PSES).

    The law set specific timetables for achievement of  discharge levels
corresponding to these levels of treatment  (July  1977 for BPT  and  July
1983 for BAT).  These timetables were subsequently revised via the 1977
amendments and distinctions were made among pollutants.  The original BPT
and BAT regulations were modified by a new regulatory concept, Best
Conventional Pollutant Control Technology  (BCT) and the universe of
pollutants was subdivided into conventional, nonconventional and toxics.

    The law has also provided for toxic effluent  standards for new sources
and/or dischargers to municipal wastewater treatment  facilities.   These
discharge categories are addressed by NSPS  (New Source  Performance
Standards), and PSNS  (Pretreatment Standards for  New  Sources).

    The manufacture of pesticide chemicals involves the production of
several hundred organic chemical compounds.  These compounds are sometimes
produced at facilities where manufacturing pesticide  chemicals is  the main,
or the only business; in other facilities, pesticides represent only a
small portion of the facility's production.  Under the  proposed effluent
guidelines for the pesticide chemicals manufacturing  industry, the EPA  is
considering new effluent limitations guidelines for existing plants—both
for direct discharge to surface waters and for pretreatment  (by indirect
dischargers) prior to discharge to publicly owned treatment works  (POTW).
These new effluent limitations include not only the pesticides previously
regulated by the EPA under BPCTCA* (primarily to meet certain  pollution
control parameters such as BOD, COD, or suspended solids), but also prio-
rity pollutants and certain pesticides, such as atrazine, which were
excluded from the BPCTCA regulations.
   * Best Practicable Control Technology Currently Available; also
referred to as BPT.

-------
Cost Methodology

    The cost estimates were developed by the Technical Contractor on  a
subcategory, rather than plant-by plant, basis.  They show the  range  of
costs potentially incurred by model plants of various flows and differing
pesticide treatability.  They were derived in the following manner:

    1.  Costs were generated for each treatment unit based on September
        1979 dollars and corresponding to a Marshall and Swift  Index  value
        of 630.  The total construction costs for each unit were prepared
        from manufacturers' estimates which were compared to actual plant
        data when available.  The total construction costs include  the
        treatment unit cost, land, electrical, piping, instrumentation,
        site preparation, engineering, and contingency fees.  Annual  and
        energy costs were calculated in accordance with the assumptions
        specified.  Cost curves were prepared for dollars versus volume
        treated, and each of the components included in the individual
        treatment units was specified.

    2.  The total cost for each subcategory was derived by summing  the
        costs for individual treatment units that are specified for each
        level of control.  Treatment costs for each subcategory are based
        on flow rates of 0.01 MGD, 0.1 MGD, and 1 MGD which were repre-
        sentative of actual flows in the industry; flows below  0.01 MGD
        were provided with alternative costs for evaporation or contract
        hauling as is practiced in the industry.  Treatment costs for zero
        dischargers, metallo-organic pesticide manufacturers and pesticide
        formulator/packagers, Subcategories 11, 12, and 13, respectively,
        are based on representative flow rates of 50 gpd, 500 gpd,  and
        5,000 gpd.

    3.  For pesticide manufacturers, a high and low cost for each treatment
        unit was introduced to reflect differences in degree of treatability
        or differences in recoveries obtainable.  For example,  in each case
        where pesticide removal was recommended, the costs for  activated
        carbon, resin adsorption, and hydrolysis were compared. The
        effectiveness of these technologies has been demonstrated within  the
        design ranges provided; however, each individual pesticide  plant
        must determine by laboratory and/or pilot scale treatability  studies
        the exact design criteria to meet effluent objectives.  In  general,
        this comparison resulted in the selection of carbon adsorption at
        750 minutes detention time for the high cost, and hydrolysis  at  400
        minutes detention time for the low cost for each subcategory. In
        this cost comparison, 12-hour equalization, neutralization, dual
        media filtration, and pumping stations were assumed to  be part of
        both activated carbon and resin adsorption systems.
                                     4-2

-------
    High and low cost were also provided where  steam  stripping  was  the
    designated technology to account for the fact that stripped
    organics may either be returned to the process  (in which  case a
    recovery has been calculated) or that they  become a wastestream
    which is normally disposed by incineration.

    High and low costs have been provided for the incineration  unit to
    reflect the fact that the size of the unit  and  especially the
    annual costs are quite different depending  on whether a chlori-
    nated hydrocarbon or aqueous oily waste is  being  disposed.  A
    reduction of fuel consumption based on the  fuel value of
    hydrocarbon wastestreams has been considered.

    A high and low cost has been provided for evaporation ponds,
    corresponding to solar evaporation and spray evaporation  alter-
    natives which are determined by site-specific climatic conditions.

    The high and low costs for annual and energy may  appear reversed.
    This simply means that the annual cost for  a high capital system
    may be less than the annual cost for a low  capital system.

4.  The flows upon which unit treatment costs are based have  been
    split into three groups based on wastewater segregation.  Waste-
    streams not compatible with biological treatment  (i.e., distil-
    lation tower bottoms, stripper overhead streams,  reactor  vent
    streams, etc.) are most effectively disposed of by incineration.
    Based on the operating range of incinerators in the industry it
    has been assumed that 1 percent of the total flow from the  plant
    requires incineration.  This corresponds to a range of 100  to
    10,000 gallons per day.

    Based on the actual operating practices in  the  industry,  steam
    stripping, chemical oxidation, and metal separation have  been
    costed at flows equal to one-third the total volume disposed by
    the plant for total flow rates of 0.1 MGD and 1 MGD.  Flow  rates
    of 0.01 MGD have been costed at full flow.  Pesticide removal
    (hydrolysis, activated carbon, or resin adsorption) and biological
    treatment (equalization, neutralization, nutrient addition,
    aeration basin, etc.) have been costed based on the total flow.

5.  Estimates of capital cost annual cost and energy  were provided  for
    each subcategory and each level of technology.  The capital costs
    for Level 1 technology, excluding corporation or  contract hauling,
    are a minimum of $290,000 and a maximum of  $4,690,000 at  a  flow
    rate of 0.1 MGD for pesticide manufacturers (Subcategories  1
    through 12); Level 3 technology is shown to cost  a minimum of
    $854,000 and a maximum of $5,250,000.  There are  four subcate-
    gories (6, 11, 12, and 13) for which the flows were in the  range
    of less than 10,000 gallons per day for which it  may be more
    cost-effective to dispose of wastes by contract hauling or
    evaporation, than to construct a wastewater treatment plant.
                                 4-3

-------
    The costs presented in this section for each plant are estimates  by
the Technical Contractor of the capital, annual, and energy  expenses  which
could potentially be incurred to meet proposed effluent levels.  The  costs
are based on the assumption that existing plants already have  installed
pesticide removal and/or biological oxidation systems where  BPT  regula-
tions require them.  These estimates are therefore the incremental  costs
above and beyond BPT.
Treatment Options
    Existing Sources

    A total of 267 manufactured pesticides were studied by the Technical
Contractor.  To meet the anticipated new EPA guidelines,  the Technical
Contractor considered a set of treatment technologies that could  be
applied singly, or in combination, to achieve the  required reduction  of
pollutants, 12 these are:

                           Treatment Technologies

                            Steam stripping
                            Filtration
                            Chemical Oxidation
                            Activated carbon
                            Biological  treatment
                            Metals separation
                            Resin adsorption
                            Hydrolysis
These technologies can be classified  into four major groups:  physical-
chemical treatment, biological treatment, multimedia filtration,  and
carbon  filtration.  From the various  treatment technologies listed, one or
more were selected for each plant  (based on wastewater  characteristics  and
treatment currently in place) and  this  selection defined  a limited  number
of treatment options.  To achieve  different levels of effluent  treatment,
the treatment options for each plant  are combined to define several
treatment levels.  For the indirect dischargers, the treatment  levels are
designated  as follows:

    1:  physical/chemical treatment  (equals PSES Option 1 in
        Development Document; this is the selected option)

    2:  Level 1  plus biological  treatment  (equals PSES
        Options  1 and 2)

For direct  dischargers, the designated  treatment levels are:
                                     4-4

-------
    Level 1:  physical/chemical and biological treatment  (equals BAT
              Option 2 in Development Document; this  is the  selected
              option)

    Level 2:  Level 1 plus multimedia filtraton  (equals BAT  Options 2
              and 3)

    Level 3:  Level 2 plus carbon filtration  (equals  BAT  Options 2,
              3, and 4)
Capital investment and annual costs were estimated for the two pretreatment
treatment levels and three direct discharge treatment levels.  The options
and costs were developed in incremental terms:  for  indirect dischargers,
the second pretreatment level includes the first; and for direct dischargers,
each subsequent treatment level includes the technologies of the preceding
treatment level.  The treatment levels for indirect  and direct dischargers
are combined to define "economic" options whose impacts are to be analyzed.
The options are defined as follows:

                                  Direct                Indirect
          Economic              Discharger             Discharger
           Option                  Leve1                  Level
              111
              221
              331
              412
              522
              632

    Of the 117 plants that manufacture pesticide active ingredients in the
U.S., the Technical Contractor has identified 51 plants that might require
additional treatment to meet new treatment standards.  (Existing and addi-
tional treatment technologies required for a sample  of 38 plants are
described in Table 4-1.)
    New Sources

    The Technical Contractor has also specified treatment levels for
direct discharger and indirect discharger new sources  (NSPS and PSNS,
respectively) for each of 13 subcategories.  Pesticides were assigned to
subcategories based on several considerations, including raw materials
used in manufacturing, wastewater characteristics and  treatability, and
disposal and manufacturing processes.  Wastewater treatment trains that
meet new source standards were synthesized for each subcategory.  The
treatment level for NSPS corresponds to Level 1 for direct dischargers
and the treatment level for PSNS corresponds to Level  1 for indirect
dischargers.
                                     4-5

-------
                                 Table  4-1

      Present Wastewater Treatment and Estimated Treatment  Required  for
                    Compliance with Effluent Limitations
Plant Code
    No.
      Wastewater Treatment
        Already in Place
Estimated Additional
Treatment Required
   1

   2
   9

  10

  11



  12



  13
Gravity Separation

Stripping, Equalization, Activated
Carbon Neutralization

Resin Adsorption, Neutralization,
Equalization, Activated Carbon
              Neutralization, Equalization, Trick-
              ling Filters, Gravity Separation,
              Evaporation Pond

              Equalization, Aerated Lagoon, Gravity
              Separation, Neutralization

              Gravity Separation
              Gravity Separation, Vacuum Filtration,
              Resin Adsorption, Neutralization

              Equalization, Neutralization
Ocean

Equalization, Not Available

Skimming, Gravity Separation, Strip-
ping, Chemical Oxidation, Equalization,
Activated Sludge

Equalization, Neutralization, Activated
Sludge, Coagulation, Vacuum Filtration,
Aerated Lagoon

Gravity Separation, Skimming, Hydro-
lysis, Neutralization, Equalization,
Aerated Lagoon
  Stripping

  Stripping
  Stripping, Biological
  Treatment, Activated
  Carbon, Multimedia
  Filtration

  Multimedia Filtration,
  Activated Carbon,
  Stripping

  Multimedia Filtration,
  Activated Carbon

  Stripping, Metal
  Separation, Multimedia
  Filtration, Activated
  Carbon

  Stripping
  Multimedia Filtration,
  Activated Carbon,
  Stripping

  Stripping

  Stripping

  Multimedia Filtration,
  Activated Carbon
  Multimedia Filtration,
  Activated Carbon
  Activated Carbon
                                     4-6

-------
                                  Table 4-1

     Present Wastewater  Treatment and Estimated Treatment Required for
                    Compliance with Effluent Limitations
                                 (continued)
Plant Code
    No.
       Wastewater Treatment
         Already  in Place
Estimated Additional
Treatment Required
  14
  15
  16
  17
  18

  19



  20


  21



  22


  23

  24

  25



  26
Gravity Separation, Aerated Lagoon,
Equalization, Stripping, Neutraliza-
tion

Neutralization, Equalization, Aerated
Lagoon, Gravity Separation

Equalization, Gravity Separation,
Multimedia Filtration, Activated Carbon,
Neutralization

Neutralization, Equalization, Activated
Sludge, Coagulation, Flocculation,
Aerated Lagoon, Gravity Separation,
Neutralization

Gravity Separation, Neutralization

Chemical Oxidation, Aerated Lagoon,
Trickling Filters, Neutralization
Chemical Oxidation
API-type Separator, Equalization,
Aerated Lagoon, Gravity Separation/
API-type Separator

Skimming, Neutralization
Gravity Separation
Equalization, Neutralization Gravity
Separation, Aerated Lagoon
Neutralization, Equalization
  Multimedia Filtration,
  Activated Carbon,
  Stripping

  Multimedia Filtration,
  Activated Carbon

  Activated Carbon,
  Steam Stripping,
  Multimedia Filtration

  Activated Carbon,
  Multimedia Filtration
  Stripping

  Multimedia Filtration,
  Activated Carbon,
  Stripping

  Multimedia Filtration,
  Activated Carbon

  Stripping
  Chemical Oxidation,
  Stripping

  Stripping

  Activated Carbon

  Chemical Oxidation/
  Stripping/Activated
  Carbon,  Multimedia
  Filtration
  Stripping,  Activated
  Carbon
                                     4-7

-------
                                 Table 4-1

      Present Wastewater Treatment and Estimated Treatment  Required  for
                    Compliance with Effluent Limitations
                                 (continued)
Plant Code
    No.
       Wastewater Treatment
         Already in Place
Estimated Additional
Treatment Required
  27
  28
  29
  30
Neutralization
Equalization, Gravity Separation,
Skimming, Flocculation, Coagulation,

Equalization, Skimming, Gravity Separa-
tion, Neutralization, Multimedia
Filtration, Activated Carbon

Not Available
  Activated Carbon,
  Stripping

  Activated Carbon
  Hydrolysis
  Stripping, Activated
  Carbon
  31
Neutralization
  32
  33
  34
  35
  36
Neutralization, Equalization, Activated
Sludge, Gravity Separation

Equalization, Not Available
Gravity Separation, Equalization,
Aerated Lagoon Coagulation, Floccula-
tion

Stripping, Resin Adsorption, Neutral-
ization

Not Available
  Activated Carbon,
  Stripping, Multimedia
  Filtration, Metal
  Separation

  Activated Carbon
  Stripping, Multimedia
  Filtration, Activated
  Carbon

  Multimedia Filtration,
  Activated Carbon,
  Stripping

  Stripping, Resin
  Adsorption

  Stripping
                                     4-8

-------
    It should be noted that impacts of NSPS are actually incremental to
all requirements for existing sources.  That is, even if specific NSPS and
PSNS regulations are not promulgated, new source direct dischargers are
still subject to BPT and BAT requirements and indirect dischargers to
relevant POTW pretreatment requirements.
Treatment Cost Estimates
    Existing Sources
    Incremental Costs.  The capital costs and annual operating costs  for
the additional treatment required at each of the  51 plants are shown  in
Table 4-2.  The table shows the incremental costs of each treatment level
above the costs of the previous treatment level;  for indirect dischargers,
the incremental capital costs of compliance sum to $12.6 and $33.8 million
for Levels 1 and 2, respectively, and for direct dischargers, the sums are
$24.1, $3.2, and $12.4 million for Levels 1, 2 and 3, respectively.   The
incremental annual O&M costs for indirect dischargers sum to $6.0 and $5.9
million for Levels 1 and 2, respectively, and for direct dischargers, the
sums are $15.2, $0.2 and $13.4 million for Levels 1, 2 and 3, respectively.
The incremental capital and O&M costs for each plant are listed  in Table 4-2
in addition to the totals for the industry under each option.

    Annualized treatment costs can be computed from capital and  annual
costs shown in Table 4-2 by the method explained earlier in tne  report.
The incremental annualized treatment costs sum to $8.6 and $14.5 million
for Indirect Levels 1 and 2, and $20.4, $0.9, $16.1 million per  year  for
Direct Levels 1, 2 and 3.
    Cumulative Costs for Existing Plants for Each Treatment Level.  For
the economic impact analysis, treatment levels 2 and 3 include the  treat-
ment requirements and costs of the lower treatment levels.  For  example,
Direct Level 2 includes treatment requirements and costs for Direct Level
1.  Table 4-3 presents the total cumulative costs  (in 1979 dollars) of
compliance for each treatment level.  Table 4-4 presents the same
information in 1982 dollars.
    Formulator/Packagers.  The Technical Contractor provided unit  treatment
costs for the Formulator/Packagers subcategory  (13) and due to differences
in the way data were aggregated, this subcategory  is handled separately  from
Subcategories 1 through 12.  The costs were developed on a model plant basis,
as shown in Table 4-5.  These costs apply only  to  indirect dischargers
because Formulator/Packager direct dischargers  are already regulated to  zero
discharge under BPT.  The costs are specified for  contract hauling of hazar-
dous wastes and for solar evaporation.  The annualized costs were  calculated
                                     4-9

-------
O _

« n
            Ics]
                                    T   o rn
                * m
                m v
                \a —<
                                            o o o o o o .
                                     4-10

-------
3 °
C *
  3 =
                       OOOOOOOOOOOOO
                                      1'
                        4-11

-------
           Table 4-3.  Total Cumulative Costs of Compliance for
         Indirect and Direct Treatment Levels and Economic Options
                         (millions of 1979 dollars)
                               Capital   1     Annual    I    Annualized
                                Costs    I    O&M Cost   I       Cost
Indirect Discharger
  Subcategories 1-12
Level 1
Level 2
Formulator /Packagers*
Level 1
Level 2
Total
Level 1
Level 2
I
Direct Discharger
Level 1
Level 2 *
Level 3
Economic Option
Subcategories 1-12
1
2
3
4
5
6
Formulator/Packagers
1-6
12.6
46.4

37.4
37.4

50.0
1 83'8 1

24.1
28.7
i "-1 1


36.7
41.3
53.7
70.5
75.1
37.5

i 37'4 1
5.9
11.8

2.6
2.6

8.5
14.4
i 1

15.2
16.1
1 29'5 1


21.1
22.0
35.4
27.0
27.9
41.3

1 2'6 1
3.6
21.9

10.8
10.8

19.4
32.7

20.4
22.4
38.5


29.0
31.0
47.1
42.3
44.3
60.4

10.8
   *Capital costs for Formulator/Packagers subcategory are exclusive of
land costs.
                                    4-12

-------
  Table 4-4.  Total Cumulative Costs of Compliance for
Indirect and Direct Treatment Levels and Economic Options
                (millions of  1982 dollars)


Indirect Discharger
Subcategories 1-12
Level 1
Level 2
Foraulator /Packagers
Level 1
Level 2
Total
Level 1
Level 2
Direct Discharger
Level 1
Level 2
Level 3
Economic Option
Subcategories 1-12
1
2
3
4
5
6
Formulator/Packagers
1-6
1 Capiral
1 Costs


15.8
58.0

46.8
46.8

62.5
. 104.8

30.1
35.9
, 51.4
1 i


45.9
51.7
67.2
88.1
93.9
109.5

1 46-8
1 Annual
1 O&M Cost


7.4
14.8

3.2
3.2

10.6
, 18.0

19.0
20.1
. 36.9


26.4
27.5
44.3
33.8
34.9
51.7

1 3'2
I Annualized
1 Cost


10.8
27.5

13.5
13.5

24.3
. 40.9

25.5
28.0
, 48.2


36.3
38.7
58.9
53.0
55.4
75.6

! 13.5
                          4-13

-------
by multiplying the plant portion of the capital costs by the capital
recovery factor  (see Appendix B) and adding the result to the annual  O&M
costs.

    For all model plant sizes, contract hauling of hazardous wastes is  the
most expensive treatment option and solar evaporation at 5 inches per year
(net evaporation) is the most expensive evaporation technology.

    Total costs of compliance for indirect dischargers in the industry  are
estimated using model plant costs provided by the Technical Contractor  and
information about the number of plants with treatment costs.  The Technical
Contractor estimated treatment costs for three plant sizes:  large, 5,000
gal/day; medium, 500 gal/day; and small, 50 gal/day.  Total costs are
estimated using the following formula:
    Total Cost =   I   COST, x SHR. x NUM.
                 i =1

where

    COST^  =     representative average treatment cost of plant  with  flow
                 size i

          =      fraction of plants of size i with treatment costs
                                        •
          =      number of plants of size i in  industry.

Treatment costs were estimated by the Technical Contractor for each size
model plant for several technologies and specifications; these are shown
in Table 4-5.  Not all technologies are suitable for plants of all sizes.
In general, plants with flow rates of less than 1,000 gal/day will find it
more economical to use contract hauling, while larger plants would
probably use evaporation unless there were severe space limitations.  As  a
conservative assumption, plants using contract hauling are assumed to
incur costs for hazardous wastes, while plants using evaporation are
assumed to use 5 in/year solar evaporation.

    Based on the model plant sizes, this implies that large plants will
use solar evaporation with average plant costs of $760,000 and annualized
costs of 211,800, while small plants will use contract hauling with
annualized costs of $4,460.  Since the average flow rate of medium-sized
plants is 500 gal/day, it is assumed that half of them use evaporation and
half use contract hauling, yielding average plant costs of $52,000 and
annualized costs of £39,160.  These are summarized below.
                                    4-14

-------
(0
•r-1
rH
3
(0
K

jj
O
(0
u
jj

O
  0)
H 5
°1«
  CM u
  \ <0
MH
as«
a 3 0>
w C
.o

0)

Is
   0
  •U U
in
I
















to
JJ
ID
3







































—







rH
(0
JJ
•H
a

o







_






JJ
C

a
o
rH
O
c
s
o
J3 0
rH in •*
_


to tn to
(1) 0) 0)
jj jj jj
to c me to c
CJ* (0 0 O"* (0 O 0^ (0 0
C 3 -r4 C 3 -H C 3 -rf
•iH JJ -H JJ -H JJ
rHtfl (0 rHOJ BJ r-HtO (0
33u 33Vj 331H
(00 0-— (00 0— (00 0--^
33 13 CM vj SSns QjVi 33 T3 Qj u
u <0 ^i IH (0 ^i ^ (0 ^i
JJ(0 >\ JJ(0 >\ JJ(0 >\
UN me UN we UN a c
(0 (0 '"H (0 (0 >rH (0 (0 ".
m




























00
rH
CM
•

H
0
JJ
U
(0
MH
&
O
U
u
i-H
10
JJ
.^
9
u

CP
c
CQ
3
to
JJ
to
0
u
jj
c
(Q
CM
•a
0)
N
rH

-------
                                       Average Treatment Costs
                                       	(1979 Dollars)
	Plant Size	1	Capital	1	Annualized	

          Large                 1,200,000                  236,000
          Medium                   80,000                   39,700
          Small            .             0                    4,460

    There are estimated to be 850 indirect discharger  formulator/packager
plants in the industry, with the following size  distribution:*
                                 t      No. Plants       I       Percent


          Large                            510                   60
          Medium                           170                   20
          Small            ,                170   ,                20
of these plants, 55 are also pesticide manufacturers with  production in
other regulated subcategories.  These plants are excluded  flora the  formu-
lator/packager analysis on  the assumption  that  the  treatment  system they
install for other production processes can accommodate wastewater  flows
from formulator/packaging operations without significant extra impact.
These manufacturer plants are relatively large, so  they are assumed to
fall in equal numbers  in the large  and medium categories.  Excluding them
leads to the following revised counts which are used in the analysis.
                                 I      No. Plants       I       Percent


           Large                            482                   61
           Medium                           143                   18
           Small                            170                   21
           Total            ,                795   ,               100
    *  ESE memorandum,  1-28-81.
                                     4-16

-------
    According to the Development Document, approximately 90 percent of
formulator/packagers do not generate process wastewater.  Of the remaining
ten percent which do generate process wastewaters, an undetermined number
will incur costs under the proposed regulation.  As a conservative
assumption, all such plants are assumed to incur costs, so

       SHRt = .10 , i = 1,2,3

    Using the above values leads to the following estimate of total costs
of compliance:

    Total Plant Capital Costs  =  760,000 x 482 x .10   =  36,632,000
                               +   52,000 x 143 x .10   =     743,600
                               +        0 x 170 x .10   =  	0
                                                          37,375,600

    Total Annualized Cost      =  211,800 x 482 x .10   =  10,208,760
                               +   39,160 x 143 x .10   =     559,988
                               +    4,460 x 170 x .10   =      75,820
                                                          10,844,568
    Cost Estimates for New Sources

    Treatment costs for model plants were developed by the Technical
Contractor for each subcategory.  The treatment costs were estimated for
new sources that are direct dischargers  (NSPS) and for indirect discharges
(PSNS).  For each model plant, high and low cost estimates were made to
account for possible variations with respect to treatability and the
hazardous nature of wastestreams within a given subcategory.  The model
plant treatment costs are shown in Table 4-6.
                                    4-17

-------
     co
     jj
     co

     8
VO
 I
 01

i-H

JJ
     C
     IT3
        en
        •o
        c
        a
        tn
     3 2.
     I










en
z
en
to

















s
53











01
O< >i
U -H
 o
rfj








•o
(1)
N
•rl JJ
i-H UJ
38
C
c

JJ
tfl
8

s

o
rH
IQ JJ
JJ (0
a 8
10

13
01
N
•H JJ
rH M
IQ O
3 0
C
s
JJ
tn
8

2

0

IQ JJ
JJ 10
•H 0
Q. CJ


C T
O W
•H .Q
1 1 t
JJ r-l
o
3 0
T3 O
0 0
U H
0
cr
tu
jj
(0
3
en


*a*
O CN
i-H VO
CN
0
JJ



CN 00
oo r-
i-H oo

0
jj

O 0
vo m
00 rH
rH
0



C- rH
00 CN
^* Cn
0
JJ

•«* rH
0 <*
CN <*

0
jj

o o
0 0
oo CN
rH CN

O



CTl
O
CN







"•




in
oo vo
Is- 00
CN
0
jJ



O 03
VO 00
CN *T

0
jJ

o o
VO oo
r-
i— i
0



OO P-
rH OO
VO rH
rH
0

VO CN
oo en
CN in

O
jj

o o
o o
m m
rH CN

0



r-
CN
CN







CN





03 O
r*» oo
03 oo

0
jj

03 CN
VO CN
in o
00

0
jJ
0 O
CN O
«# O
rH VO
0



rH Q
CO <•
>* O
T-H in
0

CN VO
VO On
p- CN
OO

0
JJ
o o
0 0
oo o
OO 03

O



00
VO
CN







OO





^d* ^3*
00 On
m o
rH

O
*

O 00
rH CN

0
JJ

o o
0 O
oo r-»
rH
0



^* cr*.
en ^*
00 •O'
1-1
o

00 O
CN VO
m oo

0
jj

O 0
o o
r» r-
rH CN

0


"^
I*-
r^








TT





m m
r- vo
in o
CN

O
*

r** i— i
in rH
oo *d*
H

o

o o
0 0
0 0
rH OO
0



r^ ^s*
CN 00
o m
r-l CN
0

vo in
CN rH
in vo
rH

0

0 O
0 O
OO CN
CN I1

0



VO
in
CN







m





CN O
•w o
rH
0
JJ


CN O
i-H

0


0







CN 0
** O
rH
0
JJ

CN O
H

O
jJ

O








t^
CN
rH







VO





o r~
rH r-
in ON
0
jj


VO CN
OO f»
00 VO

o
JJ

o o
o o
00 ••»
^
0
Jj


00 rH
OO CN
r- CN
i-H
0
JJ
en rH
en •«*
ro r-

0
jj

o o
o o
vo CN
rH CN

0


in
OO
.q.








r~





00 CJi
00 ^1*
CN CPi
o
JJ


CJ> P"*
r> in
I-H m

0
jj

0 0
0 O
in co
^
0



00 **
oo m
m CN
i-H
0
JJ
on •q-
oo *r
CN vo

0
JJ

0 0
o o
VO 03
rH CN

O



<3>
VO
r-







00





CTl VO
O i-l
•a- rH

0
JJ

** 03
in in
CN VO

0


O 0
•-H O
P** rH
CN
0



en vo
r- r~
tn •«*
rH
O
JJ
r- oo
oo r~
H r-

0
jj

o o
0 0
OO CN
rH 00

0



00
en
00







on





r^ oo
p- en
rH 00
•H CN

0
JJ

CN 00
r- rH
00 VO
rH

0
JJ
O O
0 0
•V vo
rH OO
0
JJ


VO ^3*
oo in
00 VO
CN rH
0
JJ
rr CN
•q* m
o r~
rH rH

0
JJ
0 0
o o
OO CN
CN in

o



o
o
m







0
rH





O






O





o







0





o




o








0
in








rH
rH





VO

•^




VO

^jt



O







VO
^*
•
•*


vo
^*



o








0
in








CN
rH





VO
^*
•
•sf




VO

*q*



O







VO
^*
•
•*


VO
•0-



o








o
in








oo
rH


                                                              4-18

-------
                                  Section 5

                          Economic Impact Analysis
    To assess the economic impact of the wastewater  treament options,  the
industry-level and plant-level analyses described in Section 2  are  used.
In the industry-level approach, publicly available data  are used  to assess
the economic state of the industry in 1985 with and  without the costs  for
the different treatment levels included; the costs that  will be incurred
by the industry due to the Resource Conservation and Recovery Act  (RCRA)
are ignored in this portion of the impact analysis.

    For the analysis of individual plants, proprietary data are used to
assess impacts.  Possible plant and product line closures  are investigated
for the various treatment levels with the effects of RCRA  included  in  the
baseline.  Following the industry and plant level assessments,  the  effect
of treatment costs on small businesses is analyzed.   The section  concludes
with an analysis of New Source Performance Standards (NSPS) and Pretreat-
ment Standards for New Sources (PSNS).

    Proposed effluent standards could impose annualized  costs  (expressed
in 1979 dollars) on the pesticide chemicals industry of  $8.6 million for
Level 1 treatment and $21.9 million for Level  2 treatment  on indirect  dis-
chargers, $20.4 million, $22.3, and $38.5 million for Levels 1, 2,  and 3
treatment, respectively, on direct dischargers, and  between $29.1 million
for economic option 1 and $60.4 million for economic option 6.  In  1985,
industry production of pesticides is forecast  to be  1.584  billion pounds
and have a value of $4.4 billion in 1979 dollars.1   Thus,  the possible
effects of treatment costs could range from 1.8 to 3.8 cents per  pound or
0.7 to 1.4 cents per dollar value of pesticide production  depending on the
economic option.
Industry-Level Analysis of Impacts on the Pesticide Chemicals  Industry

    The baseline projection describes the state of the  industry  in  1985
without the imposition of new treatment standards, and  is compared  with  a
projection of the industry as it would be after compliance with  new
standards; the differences between the two projections  are attributed to
the standards.
    Baseline and Impact Projections of Cost and Price

    To develop 1985 baseline price projections, each production cost  item
for pesticide chemicals in 1978 was projected to  1985.  For  this  purpose,
energy and chemical price predictions of the U.S. Department of Energy  and
information developed by Data Resources Inc. were reviewed.  Based  on
analysis of past trends, this assessment led to the selection of  the

-------
following 1978-1985 annual nominal escalation rates*:  inorganic chemicals,
11 percent; organic chemicals, 16 percent; utilities, 11 percent; labor,  7
percent; and fixed costs, 5 percent.  The general inflation rate for prices
over the period 1978-85 is assumed to be 9 percent per year.  The result  of
these escalations is to raise the cost by $2.08/lb  (or 101 percent) to
$4.14/lb. expressed in 1985 dollars.  Assuming a constant markup model, the
price will rise 101 percent from $2.34/lb. in 1978 to $4.70/lb. in  1985.
These costs and prices, shown in Table 5-1 in terms of 1978 and 1985
dollars, are next adjusted to 1979 values to put item on a comparable basis
with the treatment costs that were developed by the Technical Contractor  in
terms of 1979 dollars.

    Given a 9 percent per year annual inflation rate, this implies  a 0.596
adjustment factor for converting 1985 prices to 1979 dollars.  Therefore,
the 1985 average pesticides price in constant 1979 dollars is $2.80 per
pound.

    Table 5-1 presents the baseline average unit cost and price projections
for 1985 in current and constant 1979 dollars for all pesticide active
ingredients, along with the 1978 values.  As the table shows, the pre-tax
profit  rises from $0.28/lb. in 1978 to $0.56/lb. in 1985  ($0.33/lb. in  1979
dollars).  Pre-tax profit as a percent of cost remains at 13.6 percent
reflecting the assumption of a constant markup.

                                  Table 5-1
                     Baseline  Cost and Price Projections

                      $/lb. of Active Ingredient
                       1978      1985      1985     Percentage of Total Cosjt
                       (1978$)    (1985$)    (1979$)   1978                1985

Cost item

Inorganic chemicals      0.29       0.60     0.36
Organic chemicals        0.58       1.64     0.98
Utilities                0.22       0.46     0.27
Labor                    0.36       0.58     0.35
Fixed costs              0.61       0.86     0.51

Total costs              2.06       4.14     2.47
Pre-tax profit           Q.2J3       0_. 56     0_. 3_3
Price                    2.34       4.70     2.80    113.6               113.6
    *Nominal escalation rates  incorporate  price  changes due  to inflation,
 real  changes in  prices (i.e.,  changes  expressed in  constant dollars)  and
 changes  in amounts of inputs  to production.   These  escalation rates
 reflect  information available  in 1980  and 1981; use of more recent
 information would  cause these  forecasts to be revised.  However,  we do not
 believe  such changes would  affect the  results of the analysis
 significantly.
                                     5-2

-------
    To compare the real change in price and profit  between  1978  and  1985,
we assume a nine percent average annual rate of  inflation over  that
period.  Thus, the 1985 forecasts can be converted  to  1978  dollars by
dividing them by 1.83.  This means  that in 1978  dollars, the  1985  average
price will be $2.57/lb. and the 1985 profit will be $0.31/lb.   The 1978
price was $2.34/lb. and the unit profit was $0.28/lb.   Thus,  in real
terms, the 1985 price and profit will be 9.8 percent higher than in  1978.

    The direct impacts of possible  new control options are  calculated
based on the Technical Contractor's cost estimates. The first  eight lines
of Table 5-2 show total annualized  costs and annualized cost  per pound of
production for individual treatment levels and each economic  option.  The
cost data are presented for the entire industry  as  well as  the  separate
product groups:  herbicides, insecticides, and fungicides.  The  costs to
indirect dischargers range from a low of .250/lb. of insecticides  for
Level 1 treatment to a high of 5.99^/lb. of fungicides for  Level 2
treatment.  The costs to direct dischargers ranged  from a low of . 26jd/lb.
of insecticide for Level 1 treatment to a high of 3.77^/lb. of  herbicide
for Level 3 treatment.  Costs per pound in 1985  (expressed  in 1979
dollars) for economic options range from 1.84^/lb to 3.81^/lb for  the
industry as a whole, and from 2.66jd/lb to 4.64jz!/lb. for herbicides,  from
0.51(zf/lb to 1.92«Vlb for insecticides, and 2.83
-------





















in
41

•3
o
fl
a


0
Jj
3
s
0
Cu
0
OJ

« 2
CN 3 J5

vn O i
« 5°
«
« > ?
« ^
e „.

^
tn
in

cn
^
«3
C
— 1
S
j
I
>»
jj
tn
3
"D
C
























U
a>
tj
u
tn
Q
4J
U
u
M U)
s §

TJ -»J
u ."
0) 5
u 0
-i C
T3 O
£S
C
0

fl
c

.Q
S
8




	


in
U
01

a
y
tn
a


u
01
— i
o



	

u
±J 01
u a
41 u
— H -C
-a u
c tn

G
























	


in






"*



r-i






CN




~




_ _ _«


**»



—4

>
« M



—



"~l

	

rg


U
41



"^




















rN -» O CO ^^CNO
 r- o
T fN M
mascot S^^rti
2^SS P^-W-^r^


"* ^


"r-.voco
S^Ss^ «lr^C5(N

O CN **•> •*
1*1 fM


S^'S SSJ13
-.»» -JOiOCN
Q> ,— 1 (-1 ^
f^i r*j

OOvov r-t r* o — 4
r-i-Hysai ^r-o-^
T. ^ "1 * 04 m -H ^
0 0 \O iH
i~1 f*l


r-lr^f*4ffl MMO>t/1
•fl-moT * m m r-
^r^^-^ ^HfNOtS
fN CO f** *H
CM — <




TT CO -- 1 M5 04-•»
-»». ^-4
^H r~- i/*i tr\
M




r*-i^-(N\£i m-a-rN-H
033u^r-j ooor^
CO f*> i-* f*l





4J
«
n •—- "~~
(j r* m
r- co

N — • tn T3 — 'Jj
_* — CJ c i;
— * u; tn T3 tn 3 U1T3U5
fl - D-^a P •"• o -* at
3O-T3U-O i »T3U-D
** o u JJ u u »-4 o ^ 0
< ^ .^ u — at x -H u •-
»^ .Q 4! (j» Cu "U. .Q O ^
-^--•wtnc '"' u !/) C
(TJ 4tC3 *J 4IC3
0 "" C "
H U

\e ~*
m tr
r-4 —*



0 S
r-l O





-7i CTv
0 0


0 S
-t -H





p- CQ
O 0





S S
O O



f-v ^
CO — (
o ~<




o o
m r-
0 0






•v \n
C 0


s *
0 0






--t — t
o o

-=
O1

CO
VI
f^i


o
U( 41
i tr
4) <0
cn a1
fl3 u 73
wi U 0)
c e *a
< o
0) .-H
U XJ
<\ U 41
U
Lni 4*
51
ch
r^
Q



S
o





"*
o


s
0





tN
o





^
o



_,
•*
o




v£l
^H
0






•H
O


*
O






-4
O











w
41
^
tj
AJ
Insec



in
o
^f



£
m




tN
CD
(~|


S
^1





*c
^H





2
f-l



r^
to
O




n
-*
o






•*
o


3
n






04
^-1













n
4)
•a
u
£
£



& 0 T "J-
in m r^ r-
o o o -H



5 ^ r^ S
O O O  co r-
n ^T rH fN
OOOO




(N o r* CD
rN m o -H
OOOO





o ffi in i*»
CM 
U 1!

a -c u T3
-U U *J U
.-. ^ o ^
O " « C
w a) C 3

&


o o o
OOOO fN r- CN
^


o o o
OOOO co m 04





o o o
oooo CD m rN


o o o
OOOO  -w ja oj
»l — v. Ul C 0 U 10
CD u 1) C 3 u cy C
1 a* s: M Cu o. a; H*
CJl
Ul' 00 40
n
ul

0
(N

—

O
rN



1

o
fN


O
^





O
—*




~
o
—*


~

n
0





fN
O



—



-------
1.47 percent for indirect dischargers, 0.05 to 0.49 percent for direct
dischargers, by 0.28 to 0.59 percent depending on the economic option
selected, and from 0.09 to 1.74 percent depending on the option and  its
effect on specific pesticide groups.

    For the cost absorption case  (Case B) treatment cost per pound is the
same as shown in Table 5-2, baseline prices are unchanged and profit re-
duction is equal to treatment cost.  Percent changes in profit for Case B
are shown on the bottom line of Table 5-2.
    Baseline and Impact Production Projections

    Table 5-3 contains the baseline projections of herbicide production and
Tables 5-4 and 5-5 present similar information with  respect to  insecticides
and fungicides.  The projections are based on work done in 1979  by  the U.S.
Department of Agriculture and Arthur D. Little, Inc.  While there may have
been changes in the market since then, uncertainty in these projections is
not expected to affect the results of .the analysis significantly.

    Under the baseline scenario, we forecast that pesticide production
will grow at a compound annual rate of 1.60 percent  from  1,417 million
pounds in 1978 to 1,584 million pounds in 1985.  This overall baseline
growth rate reflects an annual growth of 3.2 percent in herbicide pro-
duction, 0.6 percent in insecticide production, and  0.9 percent  in  fungi-
cide production.  The projected growth rates are considerably lower  than
those recorded historically.  During the 1960-1978 period, herbicide
production grew at a rate of 10.9 percent, insecticide production grew at
a rate of 2.8 percent, and fungicide production decreased at a rate of 1.1
percent.  The difference in projected growth rates between fungicides and
insecticides is caused by the differing pesticide requirements caused by
new agricultural practices.  The projected slowdown  primarily reflects the
fact that most of the major markets for pesticides are close to  saturation.

    For Case A, the average cost passthrough case, the effect of additional
effluent treatment costs is to increase price and, in accordance with the
demand model, to lower demand.  The total reductions in production  expected
to accompany the treatment options are presented in  Table 5-6.   (Percent
reductions for production are the same as for profit reduction shown in
Table 5-2.)  Reductions for the industry as a whole  range from 270  to 3,371
million pounds per year for indirect dischargers, 263 to  5,908 million
pounds per year for direct dischargers, and 4.6 million pounds per year for
economic option 1 to 9.3 million pounds per year for economic option 6.
Projections of production reductions are shown for the major groups, herbi-
cides, insecticides, and fungicides as well as the overall industry.  The
estimation of demand reductions is based on the demand elasticity of -0.43
and the percentage price changes calculated for individual product  groups
shown in Table 5-2.  The values shown for those groups do not sum exactly
to the industry totals due to the aggregation procedure.  The estimates for
the groups are, nevertheless, indicative of the approximate comparative
magnitudes and distribution of effects among herbicides,  insecticides, and
                                     5-5

-------
3 2
   O
C
0
••^
JJ4I
fo a
o
••4
r^
a

a-
             O  O O O O
             00000







s



T)
<0


U
-^
w
a
ductiol
o
u
a


fl
jj
g
                                                          I ~*
                                                          D  u
                                                          >  «3
                                                          -4  >


                                                          O
                                                          «  •
                                                            u
                                                          c  •
                                                          (0 O

                                                          c  *
                                                          o  c
                                                          •O  "3.

                                                          C   -
                                                          O  ai
»
D
>
3
a*
•a
u
.u
en
0)
at
g
Of
3
3
U
cn

O

jj

ai
£


•D
a,

Q
tn



c


Ul

V)
10
JO

O
jj
>o

3
£

O
ij-i

T)
C
O
t3
OJ
jj
0

0)


(U
u
fl

tn
V


"5
>


8.
X

P^
a\


TJ
C

4


rM

01
j!E
01
u
3
T3
or
§
a.
VI
3
fl
>
Ol
4J
>
fl
-O

Ul
-.4
U)
"3



C


*C
w
cn


i
o>
>


u

c


o


pQ




>
c
o

a>

01
?
^
ft?





^^


3
tn

_

t_j

Q


C
C
Jj


— «

in
3
jj
c
if
u
I
at
u
c
a
c
-3
U
u
nj
u
c
0

Jj
u
3

o

a


™
f



0)

3
jj

a

"u

<

**-i
0


C

e

«
a.
e!


in
•-J

0)



u-
O

tn
i^


u



o
1

H




S

•c
us
3) .
3 0)
CJ --
ui tn
•o .a
in
u
i)
e
u
fl
CL,
Ol
3
jj
3
U
u
CT<
<
aj
0
u
C
at
6
ij
w
t)
a
a
€
0
u
y-j

Oi
u
US

73
01
JJ
«
>
U
~H
3
U

OI
o>
iQ
01
U
U
4
*O
C
«

0)
en
«3
tn
3

ft)

U
jj
tn
0!
Cu
_^
«


JJ


Q


CT*


C
0
tn
OJ
3
fl
>

(—
CTi


T3
C

-4


r-l

OJ
?




































CO



•.

0
-u
S1


Ul
TJ
3
_*
0)
•o

u

Jj

1:


0

qj
5
0)
K
0>
N,
^
JJ
tn
T3
C
JJ
jj
ci
u
3
>••
a
o
QJ
>
01
T!

U
u
0)
3

D

U

Vj
Oi
a

0)


u

C
£

rg
U


a
a
a

13
C

•0
O'
Jj
fl
0)
u

ft'

fl
01
Ij
u
«J


o

c
0


fl
Ll
vu
LJ
0

m
a.
3

fl
>
ir


r-l

01
t-*
c
01
u
fl
CL
s
d
01
5
uw
0
X
2
C
AJ
a
Ot
1-1
a


c
0)
£
3
U
0


1!
.C
w


-C
3
a
c
3

C

Hj
0


0)

>
0)
u

*
u
0)
4J
>U
«9

"«
V
o

u
CL

0)
TJ

U

jj

Oi
a

^4
fl
<1)
u
JJ
•
r-t
3
I-)
U
O
C
o
J-»
c


Ul




C
0


fl
S
o
iu
C
t-H


QJ

fl

1

rrj
c
n)

tn
C
O

jj
O

o
hi
a.

jj
3
C



«1
ij

jj

3
O

u

<

at
4J
4-J
C

„



JJ

3

w



*0
a*
3
jj
3
U
T
<
«M
0
JJ
c
O1
e
jj
u
*3
a.
s
3
C
£
c
.


•0
e;

fl

Ol
c
a*
m

n

c

C
0

jj

OJ
u
X
at


01
cr
C;
w
U
^J
VI
O

05



fl
>
m

cr>


u
H


or
r-
av
-H

-a

"e

>,

•C
Jd
0
t~l
a.

»
TJ
Ol
jj
•9
TJ
C
3



O

Q


C
o
JJ
s

4=
tn
15
s

O!

3


3
U

k_i
C"
<



3

C
"-
rj
— *

1'
jj




C
C
E

EG
a
•r-i
<
                                                    S    J
                                           5-6

-------
                                        —<  u-»  o  r-
                                        r~--JoriiJ
                                        (N  ft  r-4   I
•a
-«H
 O
                     O O O  O
                                     ^•5  S     f
                                     U  u jj  tn  in

                                     u  u  3  *-•  •<">
                                     rji  ^i  fj  O  'O
                                     rg  ro  -4  i fl
                                            u  X
                                     ^ ^*  rn  (jj  jj


                                     JJ  0  0  01  i-J
                                     O r» 3  2  0«
 Q
 3
"O
c
0
in
8
Oi
T3
H
•H

Jj
'J
«

c


c
Q






•C




r*

"*
01

£-<

ious issues) .
u
tj



u



„

o


£



s



ro
o

e
u
.c
u



c
fl


o

u



Jj


en
>
u
>
a
0)
13
O
Jj
Ul
OJ
0)
3
3
U
u
*£
O
jj
C
OJ
e
TJ
a



5
a
X
OJ


r-
cj\



C



r-

—


H
0)
u
3
•3
0)
U
0
u
CL
fl
tn
V
3
13
>
JD
tn
in
to
jj
T3
OJ
C
1
01
u

C
o
u

0>
Ul
0>


>*
c
JZ
H





3
(C


tn

O

u
C
>



U

O


c



c
or


2c
.tuce ) . The production data ace already on an active-ingcedient
3
U
s
*0
Jj
5
£

fl
a
CJ
Q




3

C
ji
jj

ILJ
0

tn
OJ

73
w

0)

c
I













3 (T
fj --
m «
— •* ro
•a -D
ui
u
1)
E
fl
Cu
0)
u
3
JJ
3
U
u
U-l
0
C
0)
e
D
a
01
Q
en
D
E
0
01
rQ
0)
u
V
CP
fl
OJ
u
O
*
C
ffl
0)
S
Ul
3
0!
T3
a


tn
Oi
a

^^



jj

3
O

a*


c
o
tn

3

5



ff*


TJ
C





f-(
01

H


CO
s






un








O

C
o

1r


U]

*

tn

*5

u







0
0)

o
•ate pec acce wece developed by Acthuc D. Little induatcv expect:
c
O
0
.*4
a
•o
c
fl
•o
0>
u
«3
V






0>

u


«j

01
u


-------
                                  Table  5-5
                       Fungicide Baseline Projections

                                           Usage  (million Ib.)
              Market
              Peanuts
              Fruits and vegetables
              Other agricultural
              Total agricultural
              Nonagricultural
              Net exports
              Price adjustment

              Total production
 1971
  4.4
 33.2
  4.3
 41.9
 87.2
 20.1
149.2
 1976

  6.8
 35.1
  1.1
 43.0
 76.2
 22.9
142.1
 1985

  7.0
 40.0
  5.0
 52.0
 78.0
 30.0
 -6.8

153.2
Notes:
1.  The 1971 and 1976 production data are on an active-ingredient  basis
    and are reported in U.S International Trade Commission, Synthetic
    Organic Chemicals, Washington, D.C.  (various  issues).

2.  The 1971 and 1976 export values are  reported  on a  formulated basis  in
    U.S Department of Agriculture, The Pesticide  Review, Washington, D.C.
     (various issues).  They were converted to an  active-ingredient basis
    by halving the values  (a procedure discussed  with  Theodore  Eichers  of
    the U.S. Department of Agriculture).  The production data are  already
    on an active-ingredient basis.

3.  The 1971 and 1976 values on agricultural pesticide usage and acreage
    cultivated are from U.S. Department of Agriculture, Farmers Use of
    Pesticides, Washington, D.C.  (1975 and 1978).

4.  The 1985 values  for fraction of acreage treated and application rate
    per acre were developed by Arthur D. Little industry experts  (assuming
    constant real pesticide prices) after a review of  an unpublished docu-
    ment prepared by Austin Fox of the U.S. Department of  Agriculture,
    entitled Agricultural  Input Projections and Related Information,
    Washington, D.C.  (July 1979) .

5.  The 1985 values  for acreage  (except  corn) are generated by  the NIRAP
    Model and are contained in U.S. Department of Agriculture,  Adjustment
    Potential in U.S. Agriculture, Washington, D.C.  (undated, probably
    mid-1979) .
                                     5-8

-------





•J3
WV
OJ

.0
ffl
H

1 =
3 0
cn
Ul
,-H C
0) O


u c
(A o;
3 e
'O ^
C (0
M 3J
l-p
    o

1 u  u

  -  a
  w  0
  -*  C
 -o  p
o o o o
                       t/1 05 O> •*
                       tr\ rg in VD
                       *r co tTi O
                                          o o o o  i
                                           o  o o o
                                           o o o o
     u  H-
                       C  ^
                       o   •
                          o -o  u  *o
                        C O •-- —'  "*
                        o o  u  *•*  u

                        jj ^  ^3  O  &i
                        ij —'  u  'J)  C
  c§2 J:^J  i
  0 O  U *J  u  [

  JJ •-*  J2  C1  -T1 i
  u —'  u  in  c  ,
  a     ai  c  3  1
  •O     33  i-t  Cfa  ,
  O              !
                                      5-9

-------
fungicides.  For Case B, which assumes cost absorption, additional
effluent treatment costs will have no effect on production.

    Table 5-7 summarizes the 1985 baseline and impact projections of
production and price for economic option 1 by the three major pesticide
groups.  Total production is reduced by approximately 5 million pounds,
which is less than 0.3 percent.   (If the most stringent option were shown,
the reduction from the baseline would be 9.2 million pounds which is  0.6
percent.)  Average industry price for the impact projection is about  0.7
percent higher than for the baseline.

                                   Table 5-7

             Summary  of  Baseline  and  Impact  Projection;   Production
                 and Prices for Economic Option 1  and Case A:
                   Average  Cost Passthrough  (in  1979  dollars)

               	1985 Baseline	       1985 Impact Projection
                Production        Price         Production        Price
               (million Ibs)      ($/lb)        (million Ibs)       ($/lb)

Herbicides           812           3.30             808            3.33
Insecticides         619           2.42             618            2.43
Fungicides           153           1.75             152            1.78

Total or average   1,584           2.80*.         1,578            2.82*

   *Average, based on price of each pesticide group, weighted by production.
    Baseline and Impact Employment Projections

    Reliable data on employment by the pesticide manufacturing  industry  are
not available.  Therefore an estimate was developed based on  21 establishments
in SIC group 28694 for the year 1977.  Table 5-8 presents data  on  employment
and shipments showing that shipments per employee averaged about $216,400.   In
1977, the pesticide active ingredient industry had a production of 1.388 bil-
lion pounds valued at $3.123 billion.  Assuming $216,000 of production per
employee, this implies an employment of 14,500 and an output  of 96,000 Ibs.
per employee.  By 1985, we expect pesticide production to increase under the
baseline projection from 1.388 billion pounds to 1.584 billion  pounds, an
increase of 196 million pounds.  Assuming constant labor productivity, this
implies an increase in baseline employment of 2,040 of 1985.

    Table 5-9 shows the Case A reductions in baseline employment that will
result from the imposition of the proposed treatment options, the
reductions range from 14 for Level 1 treatment for indirect dischargers,
to 61 for Level 3 treatment for direct dischargers to 47 for  economic
option 1 and 97 for economic option 6.  The percentage reductions  in em-
ployment are the same as those for profit shown in Table 5-2, since the
changes are proportionate.  The impact of the treatment options on Case  B
employment will be zero.
                                     5-10

-------
                                  Table 5-8

      Relationship Between Employment and Shipments for SIC Group 28694

                                    (1977)
                                   Value of                    Shipments  per
                                  Shipments     Employment       Employee
      Product                     ($000,OOOs)       (OOOs)         ($00Os)

   Pesticides and other            1,666.1          7.7            216.4
     organic agricultural
     chemicals

   Source:  U.S. Bureau of the Census, 1977 Census  of Manufacturers,  U.S.
Government Printing Office, Washington, D.C.  (1980).
    Profit

    Profits were calculated by multiplying production  by  the  unit profit
rate.  In the baseline scenario, 1985 production  is  1.584  billion pounds
and the unit profit is $0.33 in 1979 dollars  thus implying  an industry
profit of $523 million.  In the impact scenario,  production is  reduced
while the unit profit rate remains at $0.33/lb.   As  shown in  Table  5-2,
the impact of additional treatment is predicted to reduce  industry-level
profits by from 0.04 to 1.47 percent for  indirect dischargers,  0.05 to
0.49 percent for direct dischargers, and  from 0.28 percent  to 0.59  percent
for economic options 1 and 6, respectively, or $1.52 to $3.09 million
expressed in 1979 dollars.

    The above profit analysis (Case A) assumes producers  will increase
prices to compensate for the average added cost of treatment.   For  Case B,
producers are forced to absorb the increased  costs and cannot raise
prices, and the profit impacts will be more severe.  Under  Case B,  there
would be no impact on production, and pesticide manufacturers would sell
1.584 billion pounds at reduced profits;  profits  would decrease by  6.0
percent or $30.0 million for economic option  1 up to 12.0 percent or $60.4
million for economic option 6 expressed in 1979 dollars.
    Formulator/Packagers

    Table 5-10 shows the total cumulative compliance costs  that may be
borne by the Formulators/Packagers subcategory.

    Because such a small percentage of the  subcategory will experience
costs, those Formulator/Packagers that do incur costs can be expected to
absorb them.  Given the Case B assumption of cost  absorption,  the  impact
of the regulations on the prices, output and employment of  Formulator/
Packagers will be zero, and profits will be reduced by $10.8 million
annually.
                                    5-11

-------
   .


fl U
            c a
                       r* —i   c 3
7) f- «1
C U «4 0
~t T3 U "O
C U iJ U
0 £ U -1
-. jQ C ^
JJ U !/) —
0 4) C 3
3 — 1-1 Ui
                                 5-12

-------
                                 Table 5-10

        Total Cumulative Costs  of Compliance for Formulator/Packagers
                          (millions of 1979 dollars)
                                                   Costs
                                I              1   Annual    I
                                I   Capital    I	O&M     |   Annualized
Formulator/Packagers                 37.4           2.6            10.8
    Agricultural Sector

    Because the agricultural sector constitutes the major market  for
pesticides, it is important to understand how agriculture is affected  by
higher pesticide prices resulting from treatment costs.  The effect of
additional treatment cost is to increase average active  ingredient prices
0.80 to 1.65 percent for economic options 1 and 6, respectively.  Active
ingredient prices equal 58 percent of the price of the pesticide  acquired
by the farmer which means that the price of the pesticide at the  farm
level will increase approximately 0.46 to 0.96 percent.

    Based on discussions with the United States Department of Agriculture,
pesticide costs  (excluding application) are estimated to account  for about
6 percent of farm crop variable production costs.  Thus, a 0.96 percent
increase in pesticide prices should increase crop variable costs  by 0.06
percent.  Crop variable costs equal about 40 percent of  farm revenue.
Therefore, assuming a cost passthrough at the farm level, we would expect
to see farm crop prices rise 0.02 percent.  Table 5-11 presents data on
crop prices, variable costs, and pesticide costs that were used to arrive
at these assumptions.
    Summary Comment

    The pesticide industry is characterized by considerable heterogeneity.
Therefore, the above analysis must be interpreted with caution.  The
plant-level analysis which follows, deals with such heterogeneity by
assessing the impact of treatment costs on a plant-specific basis.
Plant-Specific Impact Analysis

    An assessment is made of the economic impact on individual plants
identified as incurring additional treatment costs.  We then identify the
                                    5-13

-------

































£
^
1
m
Q.
0

U

7 *"
- 3 S
0 °
2 f «
s s
•a
o
a<

0
w
W
0
u


T3
C
«

«1
fl 0
O AJ
-« tf)
S 3

j=
u





e
jj
yi
3


















•a o
c 'o
«j
tn
-^ c.
u --<
e TJ
OJ u
-C CU
u a
o

c
£
Jj
*
4!
QJ
O


jj
in
u



c
0
4J
fl

QJ
a





tn
c
o
OJ


UJ
•fl
in

u
e
01
o

•w
0
u
T3
"u
>



0

*
a]
ftj


r*j
U-l
O

fl





U
u


CM

0
op

fl

VI
nj
V
u
L.
a.
**j
«
01
ti
CJ
u
Ui
04
0
Q
*°
10
K
U
u
a,
o
OP
fl
01
ia
0
u

OJ
Q
u
fl



Ul
0
U
.H
"ffl

U
d
"*




^!l,04in-or---«
lOcor-oo^rHiar^coii!





                                                      O

                                                      Q
                                                             cr> cn

                                                             -«  cr
      0 c-
      U! 0
      JJ 4J
                                                                   *  C
                                                                  (jj  tu
                                                                      u
                                                                   a)  u,
                                                                   tn  u
                                                                     a
                                                                  £
                                                                  H  U3
                                                              *  tn
                                                             C  rtJ
                                                             >-  S
            OJ D
            jj e
            ro 0
                                                                      0)
                                                                  •a  u
                                                                   m -^
                                                                      c

                                                                   0 —
                                                            tn  >  a;  «
                                                             o 05
                                                             L4  •
          .  nj  u

            0  S
               w
            JJ  0
            in  uj
            0
            U  ty
               J5
:si
                                                      --»     nj --I JJ  Q
                                                      S1

                                                       a
                                                       s
                                                             o  c  c
                                                                   a»  j->
                                                                   CL c

                                                                   0  5
                                                                   E  U
                                                                   0  O
                   e  c  <"
                   3  «J  *J  >.
                  -C  «  3  OJ
               SSwaitnoSii,    <
               -
      0 u  Q  o  u
-     0 ui 0 -u jj
                           5-14

-------
ones that are severely impacted and, among those,  the plants  that  face
closure or shutdown of pesticide product  lines.  The  imposition of RCRA
standards are considered, as well as the  imposition of  treatment costs
resulting from the proposed effluent guidelines.
    Treatment Costs as a Percent of Pesticide Chemical  Value

    To assess the cost burden of the proposed treatment levels,  the
estimated treatment costs and the value of  the active ingredients  (prior
to the formulation and packaging operations) were  analyzed.   Results for
indirect dischargers are given for Levels 1 and  2  and for direct
dischargers for Levels 1, 2, and 3.

    Information was obtained on the annual  production of pesticide
ingredients at each plant and on the value  of that output.2   in  an
initial screening step, the ratio of annualized  treatment costs  to the
value of pesticide active ingredients  (using sales as the measure  of
value) was calculated for each plant.

    Table 5-12 displays the cost-to-sales ratio,  (expressed as a
percent).  Up to 51 plants may incur additional  treatment costs  depending
on the economic option selected.  The  five  columns on the left side  of the
table display the results for each treatment level for  indirect  and  direct
dischargers^ separately.

    The six columns on the right side  of Table 5-12 show the  cost-to-sales
ratio for the six economic options.  For example,  the right hand column
shows the treatment cost as a percent  of sales if  the highest level  of
treatment is required for both direct  dischargers   Level 3 and indirect
dischargers Level 2.  Economic Option  1 shows the  cost-to-sales  ratio if
Level 1 is applied to the indirect dischargers and Level 1 is applied to
direct dischargers.

    Plants with treatment costs equal  to or greater than four percent of
product value are identified by an asterisk in Table 5-12 so  that  plants
below the 4 percent level can be screened out.   (The rationale for the
screening criterion is discussed in Section 2.)  Under  economic  option 6,
the highest level of treatment, 26 of  the 51 plants would incur  a  treat-
ment cost equal to, or greater than four percent of the sales value  of the
chemicals produced.  Of the 26 plants, 18 are indirect  dischargers,  seven
are direct and one plant (No. 186) is  both  a direct and indirect dis-
charger.  There are 9 plants with costs equal to or greater than 20  per-
cent of sales and three plants with costs in excess of  100 percent of
sales.

    If economic option 1 were imposed, a total of  13 plants would  have
treatment costs in excess of four percent of sales; of  these, five plants
are direct dischargers, seven are indirect  and one plant (No. 186) is both
a direct and indirect discharger.
                                     5-15

-------










in
0)
f_—t
a

VM
0
0)
>0
C
0)
rH "
t 2
l^
« «
3 «
(0 •"
* in
jj
Ul
8
13
N
•H
rH
a
c
€























c
o
*f4
JJ
<§
u
•H
c
0
3










,^_ _ _»

u
co
U 4J
(0 C
J3 
•H (0 QJ
Q CD J
Ul
JJ EH
U
CD
!H
f^
a

	
••
CO
l_l .-lit
W fl
(U (U
u qj
(0 M
O 4J

T3 u
C ft
H
VO
m



•*T

—

ro
_


CN



r-l


_

m

—


CNJ
—





—

CN




—






H



JJ
C •
 en cs m
rH rH i-t
* -K * *
ro in CN ro
r~ vo o CN
cs
i-H
* * *
ro •* o o
[— 00 00 VO
«* in p> o
rH




^f m vo r~

vo ro cn
ro rH o
vo r- CN
vo ro cn
CO rH O
vo r- cs
vo ro cn
CO rH O
vo r- cs
cn oo
r- vo
CN ro
rH 00
CN ro
cn oo
r^ vo
cs ro





_
•K
vo ro cn
ro rH o
vo r~ CN
cn oo
r~ vo
CN ro
oo cn o
rH

m vo ro cs
•«* CN P~ r~
*
CN
*
ro o
i-H CN
O ro
CN
*
ro cn
rH 0
o ro
(N
*
ro
00
<*
0
CN
ro
cn
o
m
•K
ro in vo
rH CN rO
O 00 i-H
CN
*
ro
o
CN
cn o I-H CN
i-H CN CN CS

oo o o ro
vo ro o r-
o O tN rr
oo o o ro
vo ro o r-
o o CN ^s1
00 O O ro
vo co o r~
o o cs <»
o
rr
o
0
o
o
o





_
*
oo o o ro
vo co o r-
o o cs <*
o
0
ro ri« in vo
CS CN CS CN

in ro oo
\o o o
ro CN o
in co oo
vo o o
CO CN O
in ro oo
vo o O
ro CN o











^
in ro ao
vo o o
ro cs o


r^ oo cn
CN CN CN
5-16

-------





















CN
^,1

in
cu
i
•^
CO
EH









































ifl
cu
rH
w
o
cu
CT>
(0
4J
C
o —
M T3
cu cu
On 1
C
(0 -rH
w c
Kt 0
U
CO —
jj
CO
8

cu
N
•rH
rH
a
D
C
5




















C
0
•
•H CO CU
Q 0) J
4J EH
u
cu
u
•H
Q

	
U]
1-4 rH
CU CU
cyt >
u cu
ro t-3
£
CJ 4J
to c
Q 1
4J
-U IQ
U 
•H CU
T) VJ
CM 0^
w
vo
in


Ti-


-


ro
_


CN




H

_


ro

—


cs

—



rH


—


CN





~




i-H


c .
10 O

0 rH
00 VO
VO O
0 rH
00 VO
VO O
0 rH
00 VO
VO O




~







O rH
00 VO
vo o


O rH
ro ro

r- in on
oo vo m
CS CN
r* m o
oo vo r~
ro *3*  CS
O VO VO O
CN VO rH r-l
H
CN
• 0
rH
CS
O
rH
CS
o
rH
^J* VO O
oo in o
rH VO O
rH rH 00
ro
* He
o vo vo
CS VO rH
rH
m vo r~ 00
ro ro ro ro

oo O ro oo ro •-
vo in en en ro i— •
o cs CN o ro cs
CN r»
vo
oo o ro r— ro r-i
vo in CT* in ro r—
o cs cs o ro CN
cs r~
vo
00 O ro H ro rH
vo in en in ro r-
O CN CN O ro CN
CN r-
vo
* 00 *
in cj> en ro
CN on o ro
H en ro
ro
* *
in cr> *•» ro
cs en in ro
rH en o ro
ro
Ht —
* ro
in en rH ro
cs o> in ro
rH en o ro
ro
00
en
o
m
o
i-H
in
0
00 0 CO ro rH
vo m en ro H
o CN cs ro cs
cs r-
VO
* Ht
m on ro
cs en ro
rH cn ro
ro
en o H CN ro «*

o ro vo in
rr ro en in
CN ro o CN
en rH ro
ro
cs
o ro vo m
•3« ro en in
cs ro o cs
en I-H ro
ro
cs
o ro vo in
^r ro o> m
cs ro o CN
a\ 1-1 ro
ro
es
O Q
•* CS
CS T*
He
O O
•^ CS
CS **
rH
He
0 O
^ cs
CN rr
O
CS
o
cs
o
cs
ro vo in
ro cri in
ro o cs
en rH ro
ro
CN
0
CN
rH
m vo r~ oo

r-
o
P
o
r-
r-
o
r-
o
r-
o
r-
0
r-
o
r~
r-
o
z
o




en
5-17

-------
    Screening criteria of three, two and one percent were also  applied  to
get a sense of how alternative criteria would affect the plant  by  plant
analysis.  Considering economic options 1 and 6 only,  the four  percent
criterion results in 13 plants  (economic option 1) and 26 plants  (economic
option 6) being severely impacted.  Applying the  other screening criteria,
the number of plants severely impacted under economic options 1 and  6
respectively, are:  with three percent, 14 and 28 plants; with  two per-
cent, 18 and 38 plants; with one percent 24 and 42 plants.

    Table 5-13 is a summary of the impacts of all treatment options
regardless of the magnitude of the cost; the impacts are described as the
number of plants incurring treatment costs under  each  option and the value
of production of those plants.  The number of plants impacted depends on
the particular treatment level selected.  For example, if Level 1  is
imposed on indirect dischargers and Level 3 on direct dischargers, 30
plants producing pesticide chemicals valued at $671 million would  be
affected; this represents 18.1 percent of the total value of pesticides.
The effect of economic option 1 must be read from the  lower portion  of
Table 5-13 because the upper portion of the table, which does not  combine
treatment levels for direct and indirect dischargers,  includes  double
counting of one plant that is both a direct and indirect discharger.

    If the most stringent economic option  (option 6) is imposed, 48  plants
are affected and these plants account for 28.9 percent of the total  value
of pesticides produced by the 117 plants.
    Formulator/Packagers

    The plant-specific impact analysis of the Formulator/Packager  subcategory
uses the model plant sizes, flows and costs developed by the Technical  Con-
tractor.  The model plants were designated small, medium, and large with
average flow rates of 50, 500, and 5,000 gallons per day, respectively.
Based on an average 10 gallons of flow to 1,000 pounds of product  ratio,  the
small, medium, and large plants have daily production of 5,000, 50,000, and
500,000 pounds, respectively.  To convert pounds of product to gallons  of
liquid concentrate we used a 7:1 ratio, based on the BPT economic  impact
analysis* estimates of dry powder versus liquid concentrate values, and
estimate that the small, medium, and large plants have the capacity to
produce 710, 7,100, and 71,000 gallons per day of liquid concentrate,
respectively.

    Product value was estimated by multiplying the daily production by  330
days of production to obtain annual production and then multiplying this  by
the price of the formulated product.  In the BPT study, the range  of
   * USEPA, Office of Water Planning and Standards,  "Economic Analysis  of
Effluent Limitations Guidelines for the Pesticides Chemicals Manufacturing
Point Source Category". EPA-230/2-78-065f, February  1978, pp. 40-41.
                                    5-18

-------
                                 Table  5-13

                Summary of Plants Incurred by Treatment Costs
                               Number
                              of Plants
                                   Value of
                                   Pesticide
                                   Production
                                   (millions of
                                  1979 dollars)
                           Percent of
                            Value of
                           Production,
                          Total Industry
Total Industry

Plants Impacted by:

Indirect Dischargers
    Level 1
    Level 2

Direct Dischargers

    Level 1
    Level 2
    Level 3
Economic
Economic
Economic
Economic
Economic
Economic
Option 1
Option 2
Option 3
Option 4
Option 5
Option 6
                        117
                         16
                         34
15
18
18

30
33
33
48
48
48
              3706
               249
               450
 430
 630
 630

 671
 870
 870
 872
1071
1071
                100.0
                  6.7
                 12.1
11.6
17.0
17.0

18.1
23.4
23.5
23.5
28.9
28.9
formulated product prices was $7-14/gallon for liquid concentrates  and
$l-2/pound for dry powders  (in 1975 dollars).  Assuming  that  the  prices  of
formulated products escalated at the same rate as manufactured pesticide
prices, and using the price indices in Table  2-2, the prices  of formulated
products range from $10.4 to $20.9/gallon for liquids and  from $1.5-3/
pound for powders in 1979 dollars.

    The impact ratios are in terms of total annualized costs  to product  value
and were calculated only for the small size plant because  the impact will be
greatest for the smallest plants.  From Section  4,  the total  annualized  treat-
ment costs for the small model plant are about $4,460.   From  the  discussion
above, the daily production is 5,000 pounds  (or  710 gallons), thus  making
annual production 1.65 million pounds (or 234 thousand gallons).  Using  the
prices derived above, this level of production has  a value  that ranges from
$2.5 million to $4.9 million.  The cost to value impact  ratio is  therefore
between .1 percent and  .2 percent.  These impacts are not  considered to  be
significant.

    The analysis of the Formulator/Packagers  subcategory is based on the
assumption that 1,000 pounds of product result in 10 gallons  of flow.  It
can be shown how sensitive the analysis is to changes in this assumption.
That is, how many gallons of flow per 1,000 pounds  will  cause the impact
                                    5-19

-------
ratio to exceed 2 percent?  In this case, for the impact ratio  to  exceed 2
percent/ the flow per 1,000 pounds of product would have to exceed 200
gallons.
    Closure Analysis of Plants and Product Lines

    An assessment of the severely impacted plants—those with  treatment
costs four percent or more of the value of the pesticide products—was
made to identify potential plant closures or product line shutdowns.
Plant-specific financial data are not available, consequently  the  assess-
ment primarily is a qualitative analysis based on market trends and
general plant characteristics.


    Faced with an increase in costs, plants have the option of raising prices
 (Case A), absorbing the cost increases in the form of lower profits  (Case B),
or some combination of the two.  The price-raising option is precluded  if (1)
other producers of the product do not incur equivalent  treatment costs,  or (2)
the market for the product is weak.  Cost absorption could cause a plant to
discontinue pesticide production, although this action  is not  synonymous with
a plant shutdown because a plant could be producing plastics,  Pharmaceuticals,
or other chemicals at the same facility.  However, discontinuation could mean
a shutdown if the plant were basically dedicated to pesticides.  Also, discon-
tinuation of pesticide production at a specific plant could result in shifting
that production to another plant location in which case the firm would not
necessarily reduce its total output of pesticides.  These possibilities  were
considered in the analysis of each plant severely affected by  added  treatment
costs.

    Pretax profits on sales in the pesticide manufacturing industry  have
averaged 10 to 15 percent in recent years and, as discussed earlier  in  the
report, plants with treatment costs exceeding four percent of  pesticide
value are not necessarily going to cease operations.  The particular cir-
cumstances of each plant were analyzed in order to judge the likelihood  of
shutdown.  The analysis took into consideration type of pesticide
chemical, volume and value of production of pesticides  and non-pesticide
products, parent company resources, etc., however, as noted earlier,
plant-specific financial data were not available.  Before the  impacts of
treatment costs were examined, the effects of the Resource Conservation
and Recovery Act were first considered so that closures that would be
caused solely by RCRA would not be attributed to treatment costs.  If a
plant was predicted to close due to RCRA compliance costs, this was
counted as a baseline closure, since that Act has already been promulgated.

    Costs of compliance with RCRA requirements were estimated  for  each  of 51
plants that incur costs.  Total cost of RCRA compliance are $2.2 million for
an average of about $43,400 per plant.  Three product lines and no plants
were  identified as likely candidates for closure; all the product  lines  are
small with the largest one having an annual value of production of $100,000.
                                     5-20

-------
The ratio of RCRA costs to product value  for the  four plants  ranges from 40
percent to 161 percent, indicating a substantial  impact.

    Table 5-14 presents a summary of the  plants severely  impacted by the
imposition of treatment levels.  Part I of Table  5-14 shows the  results  if
the various treatment  levels are imposed.  For example,  if Level 1 is
imposed on the indirect dischargers, eight plants will be severely im-
pacted and the value of the pesticides they produce  ($55.5 million)  is 1.5
percent of the total value of production.  If Level  2 is  applied to in-
direct dischargers, the number of plants  severely impacted is 19 and the
value of their production ($116.9 million) is 3.1 percent of  the total
value.  Level 1 or  2 for direct dischargers affects  six plants severely
and they account for 4.8 percent of total value;  if  Level 3 is imposed on
direct dischargers, eight plants are severely impacted and they  account
for 8.1 percent of total value.

    Part II of Table 5-14 indicates the number of plants  and  product lines
that possibly will shutdown as a result of the various treatment options—
RCRA included.  For example, if Level 1 is imposed on indirect dischargers,
two plant and five product line shutdowns are anticipated and their  value
will amount to 0.6 percent of the total value of  pesticides production.
Imposing Level 2 on indirect dischargers  raises the  number of closures to
14  (a total of six plants and eight product lines) with a percent of total
value of 1.6.  Level 1 for direct dischargers indicates three shutdowns
which account for 0.3 percent of total value; imposition  of Levels 2 o^r  3
does not increase the number of shutdowns.  The aggregate effects of com-
binations of treatment options for indirect and direct dischargers are not
displayed in Table 5-14 and the numbers shown cannot be simply added
because one plant would be counted twice; that plant is both  a direct and
indirect discharger.

    Table 5-15 shows the aggregate effects on indirect and direct dischargers
for all feasible combinations of treatment levels.   As seen from the table,
potential shutdowns represent less than two and a half percent of the total
value of pesticide production.   (Note that the imposition on  direct
dischargers of treatment levels more stringent than  Level 1 does not increase
the number of shutdowns of direct dischargers.)   For the  more stringent
options resulting in seven plant and ten  product  line shutdowns  (those which
include Level 2 for indirect dischargers), two plants and one product line
account for approximately half of the $63.6 million  in value  associated  with
those closures.  For the less stringent economic  options, one plant and  one
product line account for about $15 million  (about 60 percent)  of the value
associated with the ten shutdowns.

    The results shown  in Table 5-14 and 5-15 are  based on plant-by-plant
assessment conducted for the 26 plants, which is  the greatest number that
may be severely affected by the most stringent economic option.   There
are, however, two other plants for which  treatment costs  are  somewhat
above four percent of  the sales value but available  data  are  inadequate  to
make certain judgements regarding the plants closure potential.   Both
plants are indirect dischargers; one is at treatment Level 1  and 2 and the
                                     5-21

-------
                                 Table 5-14
           Summary of Plants Severely Impacted by Treatment Costs
                                 I        !        |   Value of    I
                                 I        I   No.  !  Pesticide    I
                                 I   No.  !    of  1  Production   |% of Total
                                 I   of   I Product I (millions of  I Value of
                                 LPlants*I Lines  11979 dollars) I Production
I  Plants severely impacted
   (i.e., treatment costs
   greater than 4% value
   of production)  by treat-
   ment options.**

Indirect Dischargers

   Level 1
   Level 2
 8
19
          55.5
         116.9
            1.5
            3.1
Direct Dischargers
   Level 1
   Level 2
   Level 3

II Plants and/or product lines
   where shutdown is possible
   with treatment imposed.

   Baseline Case***
Indirect Dischargers

   Level 1
   Level 2
Direct Dischargers
 6
 6
 8
 2
 6
5
8
         176.4
         176.4
         301.6
                   0.7
20.8
64.8
            4.8
            4.8
            8.1
                      0.01
0.6
1.6
Level 1
Level 2
Level 3
1
1
1 X 1
2
2
2 1
12.4
12.4
12.4
0.3
0.3
1 °'3
   *0ne plant  (No. 186) is both an indirect and direct discharger and  is
counted in both totals.
   **Impacts are defined  in terms of total pesticide value at  the plant,
not individual product lines.  Therefore, Part I does not distinguish
between plants and product lines.
   ***Closures due to RCRA costs.
                                    5-22

-------
                                 Table 5-15

              Summary of Closure Analysis for Economic Options



Economic Options
1
2
3
4
5
6
Number of
Shutdowns
Product
Plants Lines
3 7
3 7
3 7
7 10
7 10
7 10
Value of Pesticide
Production Lost
(millions of
1979 dollars)
25.1
25.1
25.1
63.6
63.6
63.6

% of Total
Value of
Production
0.7
0.7
0.7
1.7
1.7
1.7
other is at treatment Level 2 only.  More specific plant-level detail  is
necessary in order to make a certain decision on  these  two  plants  and  the
Agency is currently soliciting that information.

    Table 5-16 provides detail on the closure analysis.  The  table
indicates which of the 26 severely impacted plants may  experience  either
plant or product line shutdown .as a result of the various treatment  levels.
The plants are identified in the table  by a) dominant pesticide  product
line, b)  production quantity, c) pesticide value  and d)  type  of  discharge,
(indirect or direct).
    Small Business Analysis

    This section analyzes  the  relative  impact of  the  proposed  effluent
guidelines on small and large  firms to  determine  if small  firms  face
disproportionate impacts.  Based on the discussion  in Section  2,  small
firms are defined as those having less  than $10 million  in annual sales.
Since it was not possible  to obtain sales data for  all firms,  the results
are presented for a sample of  80 plants for which these  data are  available
for the parent firm from the Dun and Bradstreet data  base.  This  sample  is
a large fraction of the total  number of 117 plants which comprise the
definition of the pesticide industry used in this study  and includes many
plants owned by small firms, so the results are not likely to  differ much
from those for the entire  pesticide industry.

    Using the definition of small businesses given  above,  18 out  of  the
sample of 80 plants belong to  small firms.  Table 5-17 shows the  distri-
bution of the following items  for the small firm  plants, the large firm
plants, and all plants  in  the  sample under economic option 1:  total
number of plants; number of plants with positive  incremental costs of
compliance; numbers of plants  whose cost-to-sales ratio  falls  in  a given
range; and number of plant closures.*
   *The plant and  firm data on which  these  results  are  based  are  given in
Appendix A.
                                     5-23

-------














in
•H
in
^

(U >

EH
03

4J
C
(U
(0 a)
4) >
w
cn
CM


^
O <1)
3 3
Tl iirJ
o 10
M >
CM

1.
4J C
0 3
3 O
1 H
Ul
CM
_ —
IW -U
0 U
3
ao*°rHoS$ocNc?!So§£
GO rH P* in ^3* C^ CTt t** CN CN \O CN rO in O3
rH rH m


^.^



?T^]|gua^r!i^'S^M^^l-HCfi^^*S^pr]

—
rH CN CO ^* in ^O T°* QO CA O rH CN fO ^31 if)
rH rH r-H rH rH rH
—

EH
§
a
Z
M
5-24

-------
            to
            CO
            a
            to
 to
•H
         (0

   _   s
_2 'O   QJ
 i   (U   ^
-  S   3
    S   ° jj
            o
    *—'   o ^
         01
             04


             II
                        C
                        i
                        Jj
                        <0
                        EH

                        CO
                jj
                C
                01
                           a
                               CM
                (0  CU
                d)  >
                U  01
                EH  "
                        01
                JJ
                U
                3

                S
   o
d) O
3 O
rH   «
(0 o
> o
   o

                            JJ
                            c
                            3
                            0
                        •83
                         u
                         CU
                        <4-4  JJ
                         o  g

                         d)  T3
                         Cu 0
                                u
                            JJ  d)
                            C  -O
                            (Q  ^
                            rH  3
                            CM  Z
                                u
                                dl
                            0  <0
                                •C
                            cu  o
                            Cu  to
                                    a  a o  o o  o o
                                    X  X Z  Z Z  3 Z
                                    3  a o  o o  o o
                                    X  X Z  Z Z  Z Z
                                                                                 W
                                                                                 a
                                             «
                                        a o  o o  o o
                                        X Z  Z Z  Z Z
                 <<
                 Z'
                                                                                 05
                 
                                     « CN  rH O  V£> O  O
                                     r~ o  H o  Ti1 oo  cs
                                     CN rl1  CO Cft  rH CN  in
                                     m     in p»  cs r~  «*
                                            •* CN  CM CTi  CN
                                     a s  s s  s a  s
                                     ^O r^  CO (^  ^3 ^H  ^J
                                     rH r-l  r-l rH  CN CN  CN
                                                                         EH  EH
                                                                 Q 0

«


en

—
CO
_




^t
H


»




^



__

01

5*
Q
Q
£H
D
03
cn

jj
**c
E~*
O
E^







__









—




—























ft
'O
0)
1 1
o
c

a>
U
d>
•§

jj
 o TJ
T) O T3 l-i CU
•H -H -H ft -W
U JJ U 
rH
n
«3

•H
(Q
J>
flj

c
0

JJ
(0
g
U
o
M-l
C
•H

a>
JJ
CO
3
D1
0)

(Q
C
M
*


























































•
(U
H
.a
«J
U
•H
•H
Cu
JJ
g

1


-------
    The results in Table 5-17 indicate that small firms bear a less  than
proportionate impact under economic option 1.  Only two out of 18 plants
owned by small firms have costs of compliance, none of which have a  cost
to sales ratio greater than four percent or are expected to close.   In
comparison, 22 of the 62 large firm plants have positive incremental
costs, over one-third of the total; nine of the 22 plants have cost-to-
sales ratios greater than four percent; and two plants and four product
lines are predicted to close due to incremental costs.
    New Source Standards
    The potential impacts of NSPS  (New Source Performance Standards)  and
PSNS  (Pretreatment Standards, New Source) if new plants or expansions  are
built by pesticide manufacturers or pesticide formulator/packagers  are
described.  The impacts are expressed in terms of treatment costs as  a
percent of sales.  Also, the prospects for manufacturing plant expansions
occurring in the next four to five years are discussed.  Costs incurred by
new source ("greenfield") sites are assumed to be the same as those that
would be incurred by a major modification of an existing site.
    Impacts of PSNS and NSPS.Treatment Costs.  In  studies by  the  Technical
Contractor^,13,14 specific pesticides were classified  in one  of  13  sub-
categories, and estimates of treatment costs for each subcategory were
developed.  Pesticides were assigned to a  subcategory based on several
considerations including raw materials used in manufacturing,  wastewater
characteristics and treatability, disposal, and manufacturing  processes.
Wastewater treatment trains that meet new  source standards were synthe-
sized for each subcategory.  The level of  treatment obtained  by applying
NSPS to direct dischargers is equivalent to Level  1 when applied  to

              Table 5-17.  Results of Small Business Analysis:
                              Economic  Option 1
            I       Number        I      Number of Plants       I    Number  of
            I	of Plants	I     With Cost-to-Sales      I	Closures
            I        I Compliance  I	Ratio of	I        I  Product
	1 Total  1   Costs     1 0-1%   1 1-2%  1 2-4%  1    4%  1  Plant  I    Line

Owned by
Small Firms   18          2         10100         0
Owned by
Large Firms   62          22         2       299       2         4
Total       ,  80    ,      24      .3     ,  2    . 10    .   9   ,    2         4
                                     5-26

-------
existing sources.  Pretreatment standards  recommended  by  the  Technical
Contractor for indirect dischargers  are  equal  to  direct discharge treat-
ment Level 1 without biological oxidation  (because  this treatment is
provided by POTWs) and are achieved  with Level 1  treatment for  indirect
dischargers.

    For each subcategory, treatment  costs  are  based on model  plant sizes
selected by the Technical Contractor.  Table 5-18 lists the unit  prices of
each pesticide group by subcategory.  Table  5-19  lists the plant  sizes for
the subcategories and three major pesticide groups  that could be  produced.
Note that plants assigned to four of the subcategories are not  compatible
with production of all three major pesticide groups; herbicides and insecti-
cides would not be produced by a plant in  subcategory  3,  6 or 7 and fungi-
cides would not be produced by a plant in  subcategory  8.

    The information shown in Table 5-19  was obtained from 1979  ITC data (as
shown in Table 5-18) and where sufficient  detail  was available, the range of
values takes into account the compatibility of specific pesticide chemicals
with a subcategory.  For example, the price of the  fungicide  PCP  (penta-
chlorophenol) is listed by the ITC as $0.44 per pound.  This  chemical  can be
placed in subcategory 2 only, and the average  price of PCP sets the lower
price shown in Table 5-19 for subcategory  2 fungicides.   The  lower price
shown for fungicides in other subcategories excludes consideration of  PCP.
Similarly, only subcategory 5 includes the fungicide napthenic  acid, copper
salt ($0.86 per pound) in establishing the price  range shown  in the table.
In this instance, we assume treatment of the waste  stream requires metals
separation which is part of the treatment  designed  for  the model  plant in
subcategory 5.  For fungicides, the  lower  price shown  for subcategory  1
($0.77) is set by chloropicrin which is  not compatible with any of the other
subcategories.

    It is assumed that if a new plant were to  be  constructed, it  would
produce only one of the three major groups of  pesticides—fungicides,
herbicides or insecticides.  Therefore,  a  range of  values is  shown in
Tables 5-18 and 5-19 for each type of pesticide rather  than an  average
value for all three types.

    Capital and operating costs were developed by the  Technical Contractor for
each subcategory.  The estimates are considered to  be  high in that treatment
costs for NSPS and PSNS would probably never be greater than  the  cost  for the
same level of treatment for an existing  plant.  A new  plant would be designed
to maximize production efficiency, and therefore  would incorporate some treat-
ment process components in the basic design of  the  facility;  this has  not been
taken into account in the estimates  used here. High and low treatment  cost
estimates were developed because each subcategory includes a  group of  chemicals
rather than a specific chemical.  This grouping of  chemicals  was  done  to limit
the number of subcategories to a reasonable figure. Within a subcategory,
production of different chemicals can affect the  hazardous nature of the
wastes and the treatability of the wastestream; the high  and  low  cost  esti-
mates account for such variability.  The capital  and O&M  costs  for each model
plant were combined into a total annualized cost  in an intermediate step.
                                     5-27

-------
                                 Table 5-18
            Types of Pesticides and Price  Ranges by  Subcategory
Treatment
Subcategorv
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
Average Daily
Production
(1,000 Ib. )
20.
22.
26.
7.
25.
12.
4.
76.
39.
50
5.
5.
5.
9
7
8
74
6
7
35
9
3

0
0
0
2
Price Ranges for Types of Pesticides ($/lb.)
Fungicide
1.
0.
1.
1.
0.
1.
1.

1.
1.
0.
1.
1.
20
44
20
20
86
20
20

20
20
86
34
50
to
to
to
to
to
to
to
*
to
to
to
to
to
2.74
2.74
2.74
2.74
2.74
2.74
2.74

2.74
2.74
2.74
10.44
3.00
Herbicide
2.84 to
2.84 to
*
2.84 to
2.84 to
*
*
2.84 to
0.84 to
2.84 to
0.84 to
1.34 to
1.50 to
3.99
3.99

3.99
3.99


3.99
3.99
3.99
3.99
10.44
3.00
4
Insecticide
0.77
1.17

1.17
1.17

1.17
1.17
1.17
1.17
0.77
1.34
1.50
to
to
*
to
to
*
to
to
to
to
to
to
to
3.15
3.15

3.15
3.15

3.15
3.15
3.15
3.15
3.15
10.44
3.00
    Pesticide identified in column heading is not compatible with
treatment subcategory.

    Plant size selected by Technical Contractor for development of NSPS
and PSNS treatment costs.
   2
    Based on value of merchant shipments reported in Synthetic Organic
Chemicals, United States Production and Sales 1979.  United States
International Trade Commission.
   3,
   4
Includes plant growth regulators.
Includes rodenticides/ soil conditioners and fumigants.
                                    5-28

-------
                                 Table 5-19
               Value of  Pesticide  Production of  Model Plants
             Plant Size,'
                Annual
Value of Production  ($1,000)
Treatment
Subcategory
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
Production
(1,000 Ib. )
6,897
7,491
3,844
2,554
8,448
4,191
1,435
25,377
12,969
16,500
1,650
1,650
1,650
Fungicide
8,276 to 18,898
3,296 to 20,525
10,613 to 24,233
3,065 to 6,998
7,265 to 23,147
5,029 to 11,483
1,722 to 3,932
*
15,563 to 35,535
19,800 to 45,210
1,419 to 4,521
2,211 to 17,226
2,475 to 4,950
Herbicide3
19,587 to 27,519
21,274 to 29,889
*
7,253 to 10,190
23,992 to 33,707
*
*
72,071 to 101,254
10,894 to 51,746
46,860 to 65,835
1,386 to 6,583
2,211 to 17,226
2,475 to 4,950
4
Insecticide
5,311 to 21,726
8,764 to 23,597
*
2,988 to 8,045
9,884 to 26,611
*
1,679 to 4,520
29,691 to 79,938
15,174 to 40,852
19,305 to 51,975
1,270 to 5,197
2,211 to 17,226
2,475 to 4,950
    Pesticide identified in column heading is not compatible with
treatment subcategory.

    Plant size selected by Technical Contractor for development of NSPS
and PSNS treatment costs; annual production based on 330 days of plant
operation.
    Based on value of merchant shipments reported in Synthetic Organic
Chemicals, United States Production and Sales 1979.  United States
International Trade Commission.  Value is obtained by multiplying the
annual production by the prices listed in the ITC.

    Includes plant growth regulators.
   4
    Includes rodenticides, soil conditioners and fumigants.
                                    5-29

-------
    The annualized treatment costs  (high and low values) are expressed  on
a per pound basis of pesticide produced by the model plant and  also
expressed as a percent of pesticide value.   (Annual pesticide production
assumes 330 days per year of production).  Tables 5-20  (for NSPS)  and 5-21
(for PSNS) summarize the annualized treatment cost impacts relative  to
pesticide prices for direct and indirect dischargers, respectively.  The
percentage range shown for any given row and major pesticide group is
based on the high and low price per pound of pesticide shown in the  ITC,
whereas the high and low column headings reflect the variability in  treat-
ment costs for the different chemicals included within a subcategory.

    For the direct dischargers (Table 5-20), treatment cost impacts  are
greatest for pesticides in subcategory 7 where costs range from 16 percent
(for the higher priced insecticides that can be produced in new plants
requiring relatively low treatment costs) to 73 percent  (for lower priced
insecticides that require relatively high treatment costs).  For subcate-
gories 4 and 7, treatment costs are generally greater than 10 percent
(herbicide production in low treatment cost plants is the only  exception
at 9 percent) of pesticide prices, regardless of which type of  pesticide a
new plant might produce.  Treatment cost impacts for subcategories 6 and 8
are lowest and range from zero to five percent of pesticide prices.

    A treatment cost greater than 20 percent of pesticide price is used  to
identify severe impacts that seriously threaten the feasibility of building
a profitable new plant.  The selection of 20 percent is admittedly arbitrary.
If construction is for a new plant to produce an existing, non-patented
pesticide, the 20 percent criterion is high.  However, if the new plant  is
to produce a new pesticide protected by patent rights, the selling price
could be established to recover treatment costs in addition to  pesticide
development costs  (which are probably much greater than treatment costs).
Use of this 20 percent criterion suggests that new plants for chemicals  in
subcategories 1, 6, 8, 9 and 10 would not be seriously threatened.  For
pesticides in subcateogry 2, new plants being considered for the production
of some of the lower priced fungicides would be judged infeasible—unable to
meet profit objectives of the firm—and hence would not be built.

    Table 5-21 presents similar information for indirect dischargers.   As
may be expected, the effect of treatment costs on pesticide prices is less
than in the case of direct dischargers; for indirect dischargers,  the
biological treatment is carried out by the POTWs whereas for the direct
dischargers the biological treatment is done at the new plant.   Again,  it
is new plants in subcategory 7 that would be more severely impacted  than
plants associated with any of the other subcategories; treatment costs
range from 11 percent to 58 percent of prices depending on the  particular
chemicals.  Using  the 20 percent cost criterion to judge economic feasi-
bility suggests that plants constructed to produce any of the chemicals  in
subcategories 1, 6, 8, 9 and 10 would be feasible.  Also, new plants to
produce herbicide  and insecticide chemicals  in subcategories 2  and 5 would
not incur treatment costs that exceed 20 percent of the prices  of those
pesticides.
                                     5-30

-------














CO
0)
T3
•H
U
•H
JJ
CO
,01
04
M-l
0

0)
o
•H
u
04
c
0
o
CN cn
I -u
m co
0) O
rH
jQ JJ
(0 C
EH 0)
g
jJ
10
0)
M
EH

cn
04
cn
a
<4-l
>,
i-l
(0

g
3
cn

























jj
c *
0) *
o -•
W <*>
0) *""*
O4
0)
co o
HJ -H
u
JJ 04
cn
tment Co
esticide
<0 Ot
0)
I-l 4-1
EH 0










— —




T

•
r
f



















cn
0)
'd
•H
o
•*H
jj
o
CU
CO
M
	



CO

a



__ -_



U]
a
^
•r-
c.

0
C
fc


~ •"" "™



JJ -
(0 «
3 O -
1) O
"] 1
H JJ
Treatmer















C


r_4
s


—

rH
43
O>
•H
03
	


rH
*
1


^mm
rH
Cn
•H
K



™ '"


r- (
1

	

H
Si
Cn
•H
a


"* ~


iH
g
j
r)

0
3 —
2
rH
W 43
0) cn
1| -H
a





•
0 CO
•H 43
rH JJ rH
(0 U
330
C T3 0
CQO
^ i| ^
fli M ^
QJ «_)
M4 ^H

i_t
0> U
e o
jj a
 co "^i* r^ i^* m *
rH H CN •* 0> rH O
O O JJ O
00*^0*^0001 -u
jj jj jj jj jj jj ro
oo r» o rH
^rin rHcn cNcN<*m • •
CN
rH . CN

CN •
CNrO rH'* or^** 0
jj it Q
00*00** OOI J->
jjjj jjjj LOJJJJ f*1)
. O rH
rHCN end OrHCN .•
—

CN
O . CN
CN o ro •
in in H CN r-t \o o
0 jj 0
OO*JJO**OOOI -U
jj jj JJ jJ jJ jJ ro
Tf O rH
rot rH r- rHroi* ••
" •—

CN

o> ro • cs
00 T CN ^« r* •
irt 	 i ^j i i prt GQ rt
*O rH ^^ ^> f^ " ' ^~ W
0 O jJ O
OOOJJQO4J*OOI JJ
jjjjjj jjjj jjjj ro
ro cn o rH
roro^rH«*OrH iH^C ••

O4

oo oo in H • CN
•HT^i'i'ro r~ m •
H ro N a* H 0
O O 0 0 jJ 0
OOJJJJ-*JO-'J*OOI -U
JJ jj jJ jj jj ro
rH H rH rH O rH
inmCNCNrHrHfO T»>l« ••



ro ro
r~oo[~inrv|r-)rHcN'«j'O oo
OOrHrOrHOinoOrH OO
• ••••••••• ••
OOOOOOOOOO 1 OO



«* in ro ro
romr^r--ocNininrHr~ oo
rHrHinmrOOOOOrHrH OO
• •tt*»*««* ••
OOOOOOOOOO 1 OO





r-rH^TOOrH^r^^o I oo
cncn^m^rcnror-cno inm
os«*oom'«ti-l^i1
u
o
cn
0)
JJ
10
u
a
3
CO

(0
C •
•H >,
U
rO O
0) cn
•O 0)
3 JJ
rH (0
B a
•H 3
U)
4)
i-i JJ
CO C
0)
JJ &
(0 JJ
5(0
at
VJ
co JJ
0)
T> 43
•H JJ
0 -H
•H 3
JJ •
co oi cn
0) rH -H
04 -Q cn
•H (0
JJ JJ JQ
c W O O
14H -H
•H JJ JJ
ti 0 co
C 0)
o a
JJ CO
•H HJ
CU o
•H cn
jo c -a
ro -H C
jj rrj 3
3 10 O
n m p,
•H 43
~ V4 y |
|J £• flj
JJ £ CU
10 3
rH 10
01 0
U U C
(0 0
cn -H -o
0) 0)
jj tJ jj
- (0 CU (0
e -H rH
•H M-l 3
jj -H rj
CO JJ rH
CD c a
J -H
cn cn u
•H 0) O4
a QI *
rH * *



5-31

-------
CN

in
 (Q
EH
      CO
      0)
      CO
      0)
     Cw
 cu
 o
•H
 U
04


 O

 co
4-1
 CO
 o
I
 It)
 CU
      CO
      z
      03
      Cu

      u-t
      0
      u
      (0








4-)
C *
CU *
o —
w *

04
0)
CO U
IQ -H
l-i
4-1 Qj
CO
8CU
"0
•r4
4J U
C -H
CU 4-1
e co
4J 0)
ID £4
1-1 
S^-* T c : 0) O g 04 4J (Tj L< cu cu U Cu rH (0 3 C £ r^ rH ^ rH •H rH s s — H J2 •H M rH s 3 — n •H B H s •^ rH j2 Cfi •rH a c • 0 CO •H .Q 4-> rH O 3 0 T3 O O 0 M - CU rH 1 0 3 CU 01 4J (0 O ^ Q 4J rH CN rH 0 4J ro rH O 4J O fO 0 CN CN 0 r-l r- O 4J ro ro 0 o en o o r» 00 vo rH ro 0 4J rH O H O 4-1 ** rH O 4J O T 0 4J ro 00 O H 10 CN O 4J ^* vo m o 0 in rH rH O rH cn c— CN •K •K « •K CO 0 ^i* H O 4-1 00 rH 0 rH O cn o *3* ^1* OS 00 rn O CN 0 4-1 t~ r- ro O 4J *r rH 00 O 4J VO in 0 4J rH rH cn rH O CO vo ro o 4-1 VO rH ro CN 0 00 CN O ^t m m CN •«* VO 0 4J CN O CN 0 4J 00 CN 0 4-1 rH en O 4-1 VO 00 O CN 00 CN 2 en 00 VO 0 o ^* ^jt CN O 00 ^* T 00 m * * •K •K CO t O 0 4-1 t O CN 0 4J rH O rH 0 0 ^J1 CN O O rH en rH I1 VO 0 CO 0 4-1 rH rH 00 in O CN CN * « O ro 0 4J ro rH £•«. in O in CN m in ro o rH 00 o VD ro •"* rH r- rH 0 4J m • ro O 4J rH in o t O 4J O H o 4J O « •K rH rH O o P-* ro 0 o P* [^ ro m CN 00 ro 0 4J rH t^ 0 4-) ro 'd1 2 H O rH 0 4J CN CN 0 Jj fH 1^* 0 4J ro CN ro O 0 VO 00 o o en VO cn CN H en VO 0 4-> CN CN rH O in ro 0 4-1 CN in 0 4-1 T VO 0 •4-1 ro CN rH O in rH P-- O 0 in ^t rH O o Q m VO rH 0 rH CN • O 4J 1 ro 0 • CN • O 4J I ro O • CN • 0 1 o • CN , O 1 ro O • CN • 0 4-1 1 CO 0 CN • O 4J ro O • ro O O 1 0 ro 0 0 1 0 t 0 m ^ rH rH CN rH rH CN • 0 4-1 rH • CN • O 4-> rH • _ CN • O 4-> rH • CN • O rH • _ CN • 0 rH • .^ CN • O 4-> rH • ro 0 o o — ro 0 0 o o m ^ rH ro H • k^l U O CT* CU 4-1 «s •3 co a c •H rrj CU •2 rH U C. •rH CU IJ a a £$ jJ CO (U tJ •f4 •H 4J CO 0) 04 4-> C cu M CU 14-1 U-( •rH "3 0 4-> 0) rH JQ frj 4-1 3 l-l (0 0! 1-1 CO cu 4-1 (0 e 4-1 cn 01 Q rH C m "& D3 rH 5-32
-------
    Prospects for Additional Plant Capacity

    Projections of pesticide consumption compared to  industry capacity
suggest that there will be little, if any, need for additional capacity  by
1985.  The pesticides industry overall operated at a  capacity utilization
rate of 80 percent in 1979.  Thus, while 1,429 million pounds of pesticide
chemicals were produced in 1979, capacity was available  to produce  almost
1,800 million pounds.  The components of the industry  (fungicides,  insecti-
cides, herbicides) varied in their utilization of available capacity  and
Table 5-22 lists production capacity and capacity utilization for the
industry.

    Table 5-22 shows that the 1979 capacity was 184 million pounds  for
fungicides, 888 million pounds for herbicides and 726 million pounds  for
insecticides.  The high point for pesticides production  in the past decade
occurred in 1974 when combined production of 1610 million pounds exceeded
1979 output; in 1974, about 160 million pounds of fungicide were produced,
660 million pounds of insecticides and 790 million pounds of herbicides.

                                 Table 5-22

             Pesticide  Production and Capacity Utilization,  1979
Type of
Pesticide I
Fungicides
Herbicides
Insecticides
All pesticides
Production
(million Ibs. )
155
657
617
1,429
Capacity
! Utilization I
.84
.74
.85
1 '80 1
Capacity
(million Ibs. )
184
888
726
1,786
   Source:  U.S. Pesticide Market, Frost & Sullivan  (capacity values
calculated by Meta Systems, Inc).

    Projections by Arthur D. Little, Inc. forecasted  insecticide production
to be 625 million pounds, herbicide production to be  820 million pounds and
fungicide production to be 155 million pounds by 1985.  For each of these
three major pesticide types, production data for the  last several years
demonstrate that the industry is capable of meeting the projected production
requirements with current capacity.
                                    5-33

-------
                  Appendix A




Plant and Firm Data Ordered by Firm Employment




                and Firm Sales

-------
                                                                    - A-l
            o. z
            X UJ
             LH-


              ft.                                                      -                              O






           V.
           o o
           oo    mini—Ot~ff>*-*-'<*ir>a)inujr--(j>c»
           t/> •
           Z in
           3 »—    <
           0 O    I


    _,       _«:z

    |        SS'






    1      V) t-
           O w>
    U     oo    0»o>o>o>o»o»o»c»aio»ti-r~oo*»'^u>tDTrt~pjrjri)r>u>a>


gj  O        i_    o O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O — 0> 01 o> 0» 0> at o>


&
lfll/>        	 _       .........._.__                  _  _  _   .
EH  ui        o*»oioio>O>oicipiCNC>(CNr>ir     »- in
           miu    WOOO'^OOOOOO>O'»'P>«oOioOP>'«OOOOOl~t~O           — oooooooooooooooooooooooooenoooooo
    CO     ZI-OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO — r-OOOOOO
           crino	
    K     «oO«OOOO>OOOOOo>O''ir>MOU>O«*»              »-         PI                                         Ct                   C<

              o.
              Z    QOOOOOOOOOOO--OOO — P>OnOiOOOOOOpOcoOO



              k.


              m"z
              ui O

                          i O OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOf^ OOw
                                                                                     • n {N c< in O « in






              O^OQOQOOOOPQQ«Or-QQPQOP>OOOOOOQOi

              a o
              OH
                                                                    a>    to
                                                                    »-^
                                                                         Pi

-------
                                                                             A.-2
        »
        %0. 5
         3 iw
         uj -i  — "•-'••<^~-wc«c«rri<«^ir>o>

         3 »-  •  OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO
         O O
            CL
            £
            ui
            Z
            3
       . o a
         OO    OOO'-»-»~cirl>ovTinu)(DtDinmt~O*-*-»-<1«cxu)a>»- — »-O'"«ocoo3c-MC('Tripr
         troc     •   ......   -   ........................................
         a. a.    OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOr(r«rpJC>rJr)cjujOOOOO*-'-*"'"*"*"t<'"O*ininintnr
         i H*                   ,                                                                         *• •" *~ *•» »• Ooar-u3a3cNO>o>o>oar>nnu)a)a>eNOa3inioeoC)Uip>o>i
         _l U
         < -J
         -
         OO
         >t I-
               ^>
           ,tn 2
                                                     .
                  OOOOOOOOOOOOOOO1"'- —  *-
                                                                      '
/\
O

 I
O
O
in
ui
         »/> t-
         o in
         u O
         so
                  OOOOOOO
                                                                                            cl>P)r)p)P>or>i«^-naaa)O>o»oiO>0>O>O>O>O>oi
         o o
         *_

            I-    O O O O O OO O O O O O O O O O O O O O  O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O
            «/>"-
            OO
            OO
            SO
                     l~OOOOOOCOOC
(x
O
vt
               —>O O O O  O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O  O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O Q C
         SI-OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOC
         ttt/>O  ...............................................
         •~"OOOOOOioOOOoi^ooom'-Or~ov
                                                                                               •w CD    u>o>mtnOOCJOOOci5oO
            OtB)	


           Ho    ~-^u>r-    o>»-vior««jO        in — Omioio    veoeoco'-nr-o    co»    a>««— n ID ca t-     —  — 10  CD
           ZO                    »-•••••• CM        *f'w»-        »-inr)«       «-«»-ioc>ictinr>c«^r'-
           2-'                                                n                                vh-'-                         —••««-

-------
                                                                            A-3
         *-v O.
         a a
§
H
,~
in
W

u>
>-
m
3t-    OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO — *• — — •-oicior>'«'«'*^inino>a>OOOr«nr>r)r>i-
oo                                                                                                                             .-.-,....-...-,-.-




   I    OOf~^'»m'<>''*u'*"<'1Ouinr) — — — •-•-nOeoajfNODiD'-'v^^'Cinininintninmianw



   O                                                                                                                                                  — *"




OO                                                                                                                    —          o O ••-          -fl «-

a a.    OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO'- — — »-^*---r)r>r><«t~eoeo»- — — csc'ion'rinininmininiD^
IK-                                                                                                        ____.-,-.-_..,r..-,.,^~.-N
o o
o t-


   O *"*
   oi/ioO^Otnotn^r-aiooiQ  — —•iointnnio(D^jrjnioiDcoricNiDa>ininu>iDt~





in    >-»
U)
_i ui
< -i

S £     •  •"•*"• " *"• * '"•   - °°-   •   •   •   •   •  •  •"*-"*•  •  •'"•"•  •  • "•   • ^ ™  •   •   •   • " "•   • W-   •  •  •  • "•	•
33V-    OOOOOOOO O OOOO'*"'^*^^'*"**'*"'™"'*"'*~^^^f^wc^c>irtC^cDcoo*wcNO*cooininw^r*r^t^r-r*CDr3
00                                                                                                        	__.-.-,-_.-..	^^-^w


   ui 2

   _J —	





»-    —
in H
O in
u o    O O ^J ^5 O f^ t^ t^ f^ f*" t^ f^ f^  f^ I** f** f^ f**  ^* f^ f^ ^ ^* ^ w ^ ^ ^ ^ *^  *^ ^5 n c*5 PI CP o* o^ 01 01 en 01 ^ *™ ID 10 ^ 01 oc
so     	




   t-    OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOC








inui       OOOO-»OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOcNOOOioaj'«TOOOaDOOO — Or-OOOOOO>»OOU><
O-J     	J	J	

K to               .                                                     »-          f-                            p<    »-                               i



      ^OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO
SI-OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO
ai/io----—	
«-«OOOOOOO'-OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOinOOOiOOt-OOOO —  O'ioo*"OOOcoOOOOOooOOOOOOOOdt^OOOOOOOOO




   L-


   in z
   UI O
   _l M    OOinOOOWOOOOOOOOOMOOOOOOO    OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO
   ^j    OO1TOf'O^'*O^'*OOC^OOOOc>ilf)OOOoOO    U^OooOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO


   aZ    F-       i-                                     •*"  *~ »- •- i- o>    »•       eowowooinininor-r-invinooor^tna:




   O"»    OOOOOOOOOOinOOtDMOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOC
   O«n    OOt^OOOinO— O
-------
                                                                              A-4
              o. z

              iu _»    i-ciO«o»oino>OO-»OO--or>»r>


              00    ~ -



                CL








              00                                                                 __                ___

              a tr      	O


              3 O
              O I-









              (/)%*>                                                                 «-»-w.»-^--«.».w-,-».
              IU
              _J UI
              < -I
     H      w £    r> eo  01 o> 0_ to n ^T ^ ^ ^ « m c> a. ^ ^ n J ^j "' " o' ^ ° J ^ ^ ^ ^ ^ §



     H



     O




     u
     H      r-    _
     S      !/> t-
     O      o «n
     !S      00    s>cDr>OOOOOOO^t-Oi-r-r>ir*a>eDsoeoniDOO

     O      St3      """0*0	'	do	— —


iN    *        ^ ^~                               -

^   in        K    OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO-^'	— — — — Q> 0> 0>





     JJL       ^o-"-                     n    w r< «

     ui       t— •«/»
              Vitti    OO  — OOOOOUJOo>OOr>OOO'»^ionOOOOOOOiO»»f-O
              O—i      ••«•>	'	



     u.

     >           -.OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOCTOO
     ffl      Sl-OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO'-OOOOOOr-OO
              Qft/IO**'**   ......,............_........

     OC       IL.O**       r^               ^J'"       —          OO*O*~*0®          'T^**
     O           *^       O               wc(                   *™^c(^rc>*          co^^
     I/)                    CJ               *-                                             W          C<

                 o.
                 Z    O"-OOO«nO«nOOOOOOO'»OOOr>o<*~OOU>OC')OOOOO


                 oc    wc*tor"3Uitf>*or*>con^>tDOOOio*"*"P5C3U3O^inoc*)tniort^o>c*ci

                 u.                                                                                *• *~ »- »- — •-•


                 uiz
                 ui O

                 4d
                 2*Hio^>Oo>incoooo^QjOiD*~ioOwioo*Otor*^Dioo*tftOr*>odOOO





                 O<-»O«OOOOOOOOOOOl^OOOnOOOOOOOOOOOOOO
                 OU)O«r~OOOOoo«Dt^OOO'T*-OOt-tf>OOOOOOOOOOOOco
                 OH
                 CU

-------
             Appendix B




Derivation of Capital Recovery Factor

-------
                                 Appendix B

                    Derivation  of  Capital  Recovery  Factor


    The capital recovery factor (CRF) measures the rate of return that an
investment must achieve each year in order to cover the cost of the invest-
ment and maintain net earnings, including depreciation and taxes.  Stated
another way, the capital recovery factor is the excess of revenues over
variable costs, per dollar of invested capital, needed to cover the cost of
borrowing, depreciation and net profit-related taxes, while preserving the
market value of the firm's stock.

    The formula for CRF used in previous analyses was:
                  A(N,K,) - td
          CRF  =  - 1 -                        (B-l)
                     1 - t

where:

    N         =  lifetime of investment
    Kf        =  average after-tax cost of capital
    A(N,Kf)   =  annuity whose present value is 1,
                   given N and Kf [Kf/(l-(l+Kf
    d         =  depreciation rate
    t         =  corporate income taxes

Changes in the tax code dealing with rapid depreciation and investment tax
credits, require alterations in the formula for calculating the capital
recovery factor.  The revised formula is:

                  A(N,Kf)(.9-c)
          CRF  =  - 1 -                       (B-2)
                     1 - t
where:      c  =   E
where:

       n|     =  depreciation lifetime under tax code
       d'      = new depreciation rate

       Other variables as above.

The derivation of these formulas are given in the back of this Appendix.
The assumptions and data used to obtain values for the above variables are
described below.

    A single, industry-wide CRF equal to 21.8 percent has been used in our
analysis.  For a given investment, a firm's CRF will vary with their cost
of capital and mix of financing.  However, it was not possible to estimate
a separate CRF for each establishment or firm.

-------
    Average Cost of Capital

    The cost of capital, Kf, is the average percentage return that
suppliers of debt and equity demand.  For firms which have more than one
type of capital, Kf is calculated as the average of the after-tax costs
of debt and the costs of equity, weighted by the share of market value of
each relative to the total market value of the firm.  In equation form:
          K*  =  bi(l-t) + (l-b)r                     (B-3)
where:
       Kf   =  average cost of capital after taxes
       i    =  average of cost of debt
       r    =  average cost of equity
       t    =  corporate income tax rate
       b    =  share of debt financing

    The costs of debt and equity are measured by the current market value
of outstanding debt and stock, rather than the original costs when the
debt and equity were issued.  The argument that projects should be eval-
uated using the weighted average cost of capital as the discount factor
has been made elsewhere* and rests on several assumptions. Firms are
assumed to have an optimal debt/equity ratio (or at least some preferred
debt/equity ratio), to have already obtained that ratio, and to strive to
maintain it over time.  In addition, it is assumed that new projects do
not alter the overall risk position of the firm.  (A change in the risk
level might result in a change in the debt/equity level.)  Therefore, new
projects, on average, will be financed with these same desired fractions
of debt and equity.


    Cost of Debt.  Since firms often have more than one debt issue, it is
necessary to calculate an average cost within a company as well as across
companies.  The following information on the debts of 40 chemical
companies was obtained from Standard and Poor's Bond Guide (August 1979).**
    1)  yield to maturity
    2)  debt outstanding
    3)  closing price
    First, the total market value of each bond issue is calculated as the
bond price multiplied by the amount of debt outstanding.  Second, the
average cost of debt is calculated as a weighted average of the various
   *See, for example, J. Fred Weston and Eugene F. Brigham, Managerial
Finance (6th ed.), Dryden Press, 1978, Chapter 19.
   **See:  Draft Industry Description:  Organic Chemical Industry, Vol. I,
December 1979, pages 3-7 through 3-16, for a detailed presentation of the
data.

                                     B-2

-------
values for yield to maturity, where the weights equal the ratio of the
market value of each bond issue to the total value of debt.  The average
before-tax cost of debt for these companies is 9.89 percent.


    Cost of Equity.  A firm's cost of equity can be expressed in equation
form as:

          r  =  — + g                               (B-4)
                 P
where e is the annual dividend, P is the stock price, and g the expected
growth rate of dividends.*  To estimate the firms' cost of equity, the
following data were obtained from Standard and Poor's Stock Guide (August
1979):

    1}  dividend yield;
    2)  closing price;
    3)  number of shares outstanding.

    Information was collected for common stocks.  The existence of
preferred stocks complicates the calculations substantially, since a
preferred stock is more nearly a stock-bond hybrid.  Preferred stocks are
ignored except where they represent more than 10 percent of the market
value of all stocks.  In those cases where preferred socks represent a
signficiant portion of equity, the company was removed from the survey.

    An estimate of the expected growth rate was obtained using data from
the USITC Organic Chemicals (1977) and the DRI Chemical Review.  A
weighted average of annual growth rates for plastics, fibers, and
elastomers sales was obtained for the entire industry:

          g  =  .745(7.1 ) + .125(1.6 ) + .130(3.8 )  =  6.0
                 Plastics    Elastomers      Fibers
    Depreciation

    Depreciation is normally defined as the fraction of revenues set aside
each year to cover the loss in value of the capital stock.  Due to recent
changes in the federal tax code, the economic life of a capital item is
now considerably longer than the depreciation life for tax purposes.
Based on earlier work the lifetime of capital stock for this industry is
assumed to be about 10 years.*  The depreciation rate for most personal
property now is straight-line over five years (20  ).  These values are
used in the revised calculation of the capital recovery factor.
    ''See, for example, J. Weston and F. Brigham, op.cit.
                                     B-3

-------
    Tax Rate

    The current federal corporate income tax rate is 20 percent on the
first 225,000 of profits, 22 percent on the next $25,000, and 46 percent
on all profits over $50,000.  For this analysis, we assume that plants are
paying an even 46 percent federal tax on all profits.  A study by Lin and
Leone** indicates that state and local income taxes also are a significant
factor in pollution control investments.  State corporate income tax rates
may be as high as 9.5 percent.  In their study, a weighted average of 7
steel-producing states yielded an average state corporate income tax rate
of 7.55 percent.  State income taxes, of course, are deductible expenses
in computing corporate income tax.  We assume a state corporate income tax
rate of 8 percent.  Deducting this figure before computing the federal
income tax rate reduces the net effect of the 8 percent rate to about 4
percent.  Thus, the overall effective income tax rate is approximately 50
percent.


    Sensitivity Analysis

    Table 1 presents various values for the capital  recovery factor,
assuming various weighted costs of capital   (Kf) and different
formulations allowing for changes in the federal tax code.  Both the rapid
depreciation and the investment tax credit serve to lower the capital
recovery factor, thus reducing the return necessary to justify a given
investment.

    In previous work in both the pulp and paper industry and the organic
chemical industry, we have estimated the weighted cost of capital based on
the current costs as reflected in the current prices and yields of a
sample of corporate stocks and bonds for that industry.  In August of
1979, the weighted cost of capital for the organic chemical industry was
estimated to be about 10 .  There are two major assumptions in using this
method.  First that current prices and yields accurately reflect future
costs of capital.  However, interest rates have increased significantly
since the summer of 1979.  Second, that the current portfolio mix will
remain constant over the next several years.  Given changes in tax codes,
and changes in the availability of certain sources of capital such as
industrial revenue bonds, this is unlikely.  Therefore we expect that the
cost of capital will be higher than 10 percent.  Given the mix of financ-
ing sources available, it is unlikely to be as high as 15 percent and we
believe that 13 percent is a good estimate of the weighted cost of capital
for the period covered by this study.
   *Draft Industry Description:  Organic Chemical Industry, Vol. I,
December 1979.

   **An Loh-Lin and Robert A. Leone, "The Iron and Steel Industry," in
Environmental  Controls, (Robert A. Leone, ed.), Lexington, MA:  Lexington
Books U976), p. 70.
                                     B-4

-------
Variable
                      Table B-l
Alternative Derivations of the Capital  Recovery Factor

                                     Values
Weighted cost of
  capital (K,.)
Life of asset (N)
A(M, Kf)
Depreciation life (n)
Depreciation rate (d)
Tax rate (t)
c
CRF(l)
CRF(2)
CRF(3)
                  .10    .15    .20    .10    .13    .15    .20

                10     10     10     10     10     10     10
                  .163   .199   .239   .163   .185   .199   .239
                10     10     10      5      5      5      5
                  .10    .10    .10    .20    .20    .20    .20
                  .50    .50    .50    .50    .50    .50    .50
                                       .330   .310   .300   .275
                  .226   .298   .378
                                       .218   .255   .279   .347
                                       .185   .218   .239   .299
where:  CRF(l) is original formula (2-1 in text)
        CRF(2) allows for rapid depreciation but not investment tax credit
        CRF(3) allow for both rapid depreciation and investment tax credit
        (2-2 in text)
                                    B-5

-------
Original Form

    The capital recovery factor can be expressed analytically as follows.
Let:
         R       =   annual revenue
         C       =   annual variable costs:  labor, materials, energy, etc.
         I       =   investment cost
         *       =   capital recovery factor = (R-O/I
         d       =   depreciation rate
         t       =   tax rate
         Kf      =   weighted cost of capital (after-tax)
         N       =   investment lifetime in years
         A(Kf,N) =   annuity whose present value equals 1, given discount
                     rate Kf and lifetime N.

    Given revenues and direct costs, average cost of capital, tax rates,
depreciation rates, and investment lifetime, the problem is to find that
gross return per dollar of invested capital which allows the firm to just
cover its costs of capital, depreciation, and taxes and maintain the value
of the firm.  Equation (B-5) expresses the relationship that must hold for
the firm to break even on its invested capital,  I.  In other words, the
present discounted value of the net income flow (using the average cost of
capital as the discount factor) just equals the cost of the firm's initial
investment:

               N
               Z    (R-C) - t(R-C) + tdl              (5-5)
The numerator of the left-hand side of equation (B-5) shows net profits
plus the tax subsidy on depreciation.  Note that the tax subsidy on
interest payments is not included because it is already taken into account
by using the after-tax cost of debt in the average cost of capital.
Dividing equation (B-5) by I and substituting IT for (R-O/I gives:

               N
               Z   IT - tir + td   .,                     (B-6)

              0=1   (1 * Kf)J

Note that if the numerator is assumed constant (i.e., constant R-C,
depreciation and tax rates) over all periods, it represents the annuity
whose present value is 1, given discount rate Kf and lifetime N, i.e.,
A(Kf,N).  We can then "solve" equation (B-6) for IT using the tables for
"Annuity whose Present Value is 1."  Then ir will be the "capital recovery
factor," expressed as a percentage of initial investment, which must be
added to direct operating costs to ensure the project return equals its
cost of capital.  The result is given below:

               it - t* + td = A(Kf,N)
                                     B-6

-------
                   A(K,,N) - td
                   - - -                     (B-7)
                       1  - t
Alternative Form
    The 1981 tax reform  act allows firms to depreciate capital  stock for
tax purposes at a rate faster than depreciation for economic  purposes.
Therefore d is no longer the inverse of N as above.  In addition, a 10
tax credit is allowed on new investments, thus reducing the  initial cost
of the investment to 90   of its original cost.  Therefore, equation (B-6)
above becomes:
              N
              V  IT  -  tlT
                                      = .9             (B-8)
where:
    n  = depreciation lifetime under tax code
    d1 = new depreciation  rate
    Setting:
                n
                       td1
               1=1    (1V=C
    Then:
                E   *  "  tir  , =  .9-C                      (B-9)
N
Z (TT - ti
= 1 (1
t) / (.9-C)
+ Kf)J
= 1
Assuming as before  that  the numerator is a constant over  all periods, it
represents the  annuity whose present value is 1,  given  discount rate Kf
and lifetime N.
                                    B-7

-------
Therefore:
                —2	L_ = A(K  ,N)
                 .9-C     .9-C      f

                  (_kl_)   = A(K  ,N)                   (B-ll)
                   .9-C         f

                   A(K,M)(.9-C)                     (B

                         1-t
                                       B-8

-------
Appendix C




References

-------
                                References
 1.   U.S.  International Trade Commission, Synthetic Organic Chemicals,
     1977, U.S. Government Printing Office, Washington, D.C., 1978.

 2.   Arthur D. Little Inc., unpublished information furnished by E.P.A.

 3.   Bureau of the Census, 1977 Census of Manufacturers, U.S. Government
     Printing Office, Washington, D.C., 1980.

 4.   Radian Corp., Industrial Process Profiles for Environmental Use:
     Chapter 8 - Pesticides Industry, Parson, T.B., ed., National
     Technical Information Service, Springfield, VA, PB-266 255, January
     1977.

 5.   Production, import, and export values calculated from U.S.
     Department of Agriculture.  The Pesticide Review, Washington, D.C.,
     various issues.

 6.   Agricultural pesticide usage figures taken from Reference 7.

 7.   Carlson, G.A., Long-Run Productivity of Insecticides,  American
     Journal of Agricultural Economics, 59, 3, August 1977, pp. 543-548.

 8.   Meta Systems, Inc Memorandum for the Organic Chemicals file, October
     22, 1981.
                                                       t
 9.   Meta Systems, Inc Memorandum to E.P.A., "Effect of RCRA Costs on
     Pesticide Plant Closures", dated October 11, 1981.

10.   Meta Systems, Inc Memorandum to E.P.A., "Pesticide Plant and Product
     Line Closures", dated January 29, 1982.

12.   Environmental Services and Engineering, Inc.  (ESE) Revised
     Contractor Report for Best Available Technology, Pretreatment
     Technology, New Source Performance Technology and Best Correlational
     Pollution Control Technology in the Pesticide Chemicals Industry,
     November 1980, est. No. 79-238-001.

13.   ESE Memorandum dated January 7, 1981, subject:  Revised New Source
     Performance Standards Cost.

14.   ESE Memorandum dated January 19, 1981, subject:  Additional NSPS
     Product Information, Pesticides BAT Reviews.

15.   Frost and Sullivan U.S. Pesticides Market.

16.   Pimental, D., et al.  Benefits and Costs of Pesticide Use in U.S.
     Food Production, Bioscience, December 1978, pp. 772-783.

-------
                                   C-2
                                References
                                (continued)
17.  Eichers/ T., Andrilenasr P., and W. Anderson, T.W., Farmer's Use  of
     Pesticides in 1976, USDEA, Washington, various issues.

18.  Federal Trade Commission, Quarterly Financial Report, U.S.
     Government Printing Office, Washington, D.C., various issues.

19.  William Blair & Company, The Pesticide Industry:  An Overview,
     Chicago, Illinois, 1975.

20.  Goring C., The Costs of Commercializing Pesticides, in Pesticide
     Management and Insecticide Resistance, Harcourt Brace Jovanovich,
     New York, 1977, pp. 1-33.

21.  Arthur D. Little, Inc., Evaluation of the Possible Impact of
     Pesticide Legislation on Research and'Development Activities of
     Pesticide Manufacturers, Report to Office of Pesticide Programs,
     EPA, 1975.

22.  C. H. Kline & Co., The Kline Guide to the Cheaical Industry, Fourth
     Edition, Industrial Marketing Guide IMG 13-80.

23.  Economic Information Systems, Inc. On-Line Data Base.

24.  Dun and Bradstreet Million Dollar Directory, 1981.

-------