OCR error (C:\Conversion\JobRoot\00000AOF\tiff\2000W9I0.tif): Unspecified error

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
I
I
I
I
GEOME T, INCORPORATED . is FIRSTFIELD ROAD • GAITHERSBURG, MARYLAND 20750
                                              301/948-0755 • CABLE ADDRESS: GEOMETINC
                                      August 1,  1979
  Mr. Thomas  DeMoss
  Chesapeake  Bay  Program
  U.S.  Environmental  Protection  Agency
  2083  West Street
  Annapolis,  Maryland 21401

  Dear  Mr. DeMoss:

            Enclosed  are  the  results  of the  literature search on "Socio-
  economic Analysis with  Respect to Large  Scale Water Resources  Planning
  and Usage"  we have  completed for your office.   This search was undertaken
  on July 16,  1979 under  GEOMET's Task Order Contract with EPA,  68-01-4144.

            This  search focuses  on the overall  topic  by taking the following
  steps.  First,  two  computerized bibliographic searches were conducted
  for the period  1971  to  the  present.   Included were  searches of the National
  Technical Information Service  System, and  of  Enviroline, a data base containing
  citations from  all  the  major environmentally  oriented journals.  Second,  an
  independent hand search was conducted of journals and books outside the
  environmental field.  A variety of  published,  special topic bibliographies
  concerned with  methods  of economic  analysis in large scale public programs
  were  consulted  during this  step.

            The results of this  three week effort are organized  in the following
  four  sections:
                                                          *

            t    Publicly financed research  projects  with abstracts
                  of their results

            •    Photo copies of articles  of particular relevance
                  to the sodo-economics of water resource use

            •    A bibliography  of journal articles,  books, book
                  chapters, and professional  presentations of relevance

            •    Books of special relevance  which EPA might consider
                  acquiring for its own library.

            We have appreciated  this  opportunity to assist EPA and hope we
  can be of further service in the near future.   If you have questions concerning

-------
Mr. Thomas DeMoss
-2-
August 1, 1979
this bibliographic search, please do not hesitate to call  me at
(301) 948-0755.
MBHrltg

Enclosure
                                   Michael  B.  Harrington,  Ph.D.
                                   Manager, Health and Environmental
                                     Economics Studies

-------

-------
1
1

1

1
^p
1
V




1




1











1


1
1
1
1
1


TABLE OF CONTENTS


1.0 PUBLICLY FINANCED RESEARCH PROJECTS
WITH ABSTRACTS
1.1 Alphabetical Listing of Economic
Analysis Abstracts
1.2 Economic Analysis Abstracts
1.3 Alphabetical Listing of Socio-Political
Analysis Abstracts
1.4 Socio-political Analysis Abstracts
1.5 Alphabetical Listing of Methodology
Abstracts
1.6 Methodology Abstracts
1.7 Alphabetical Listing of Environmental
Case Studies Abstracts
1.8 Environmental Case Studies Abstracts
2.0 RELEVANT PHOTOCOPIED ARTICLES
2.1 Alphabetical Listing of Economic
Analysis Articles
2.2 Economic Analysis Articles
2.3 Alphabetical Listing of Socio-Political
Analysis Articles
2.4 Socio-Political Analysis Articles
2.5 Alphabetical Listing of Methodology Articles
2.6 Methodology Articles
2.7 Alphabetical Listing of Environmental Case
Studies Articles
2.8 Environmental Case Studies Articles
3.0 A SUPPLEMENTARY BIBLIOGRAPHY
4.0 RECOMMENDED" ADDITIONS TO EPA'S LIBRARY





V




Page
1-1

1-2

1-3
1-20

1-22
1-42
1-44
1-73

1-76
2-1
2-2

2-3
2-139

2-140
2-249
2-250
2-307

2-307
3-1
4-1







-------
I
I
I
i
i
i
i
i
i
                                              Section 1.0
I
                           PUBLICLY FINANCED RESEARCH PROJECTS WITH ABSTRACTS

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

-------
 I

 I
 I                                       Section 1.0
                       PUBLICLY FINANCED RESEARCH PROJECTS WITH ABSTRACTS

                       Included 1n this section are the abstracts of research projects
 •          funded by public authorities, typically the Federal government.  All  were
             obtained through a search of the computerized files maintained by the
 B          National Technical Information Service in Springfield, Virginia.  These
 •          project abstracts are organized in four sections:  economic analysis;
             socio-political  analysis; methodology; and environmental case studies.
 •          Many of the projects could appear under several headings due to their
             breadth or for other reasons.  Nonetheless, each project appears just
 •          once, under the heading which appears to express its major thrust most
 •          effectively.   Within each section, the projects are alphabetized by title.

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

1

I

-------
 1.1   Alphabetical  Listing of Economic Analysis  Abstracts
 1.   An Analytical  Interdisciplinary Evaluation  of the Utilization of the
     Water Resources of the Rio Grande in New Mexico:   Lower Rio Grande
     Region.
 2.   Analyzing Reimbursement Mechanisms of Resource Development Project.
 3.   Alternate Solutions to Water Resource Development—A  Case Study.
 4.   Commercial Navigation on the Upper Mississippi River:  An Economic
     Review of Its  Development and Public Policy Issues Affecting Minnesota,
 5.   Economic Base  Study of the Mobile-Alabama-Coosa River Basin.
 6.   An Economic Analysis of the Proposed Water  Resources  Project for
     the Upper French Broad River Basin in Western North Carolina.
 7.   An Economic Evaluation of Water Quality Management Systems.
 8.   Effects of Economic Development on Water Resources.
 9.   The Interrelationship of Economic Development and Environmental
     Quality 1n the Upper Colorado River Basin:   An Interindustry Analysis.
10.   A Methodology  for Assessment of Water Resources Development:  A
     Competitive Evaluation Model for Water Resources  Development Planning.
11.   People and the Sound.  An Economic Perspective.
12.   Plan for Development of the Land and Water  Resources  of the Southeast
     River Basins.   Appendix 9.  Economics.
13.   The Powder River Basin Economic Simulation  Model:  A  Technical Report
     and Supplement to the Technical Report.
14.   Research on Water Resources Evaluation Methodology:  A River Basin
     Economic and Financial Post-Audit.
15.   Subsidies, Capital Formation, and Technological Change:  Municipal
     Wastewater Treatment Facilities.   Volume 1.
16.   The Willamette Basin Comprehensive Study of Water and Related Land
     Resources.  Appendix C.  Economic Base.
                                   1-2

-------
I
I
_           1.2  Economic Analysis Abstracts

I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I

-------
An  Analytical Interdisciplinary Evaluation of the Utilization
of the Water Resources of the Rio Grande in New Mexico:  Lower
Rio Grande Region

                    Univ.,   University ParK.  Water Resources
           Flci:
         122p
         WRRI-024
         OWRR-A-045-NMEX, OWRR-B-016-NMEX
   Bon-David, Shaul; Gebhard, Thomas
CreeI,  Booby J.
 GRAI7414
Now  Mexico  State
Research Inst.
AUTHOR: Lansford, Robert R.
G. Or; Brutsacrt, Willem
C2945H4    Fid: 138, 488
May 73
Rept No
Project
Moni tor: OWRR-A-045-rJMEX(6)
Includes Rept. nos. CWRR-B-019-NMEX(6) and OWRR-8-026-NMEX(6).
Abstract: An interdisciplinary approach to the solution of the
water resource problems of the Lower Rio Grande Region in  New
Mexico  was centered around a socio-economic model, 'developed
to represent the Me.v Mexico economy,   witn  special  emphasis
placed   upon   the   Rio  Granae  region.   Inputs  into  the
socio-economic  model  were  obtained  from  separate  studies
covering  the  hydrological,    agricultural,   municipal,  and
industrial areas.   Three sets of alternatives were considered:
Growth   without   a   water    constraint;   growth,   with  a
surface-water constraint;  growth,  with  both  surface-   and
ground-water constraints. (Modified author abstract)

Descriptors:   *New  Mexico,   *Rio Grande River Basin,  *Water
resources,   River  basin  development,   Economic   analysis,
Forecasting,  Economic models,  Surface waters,  Ground water,
Land use, Classifications, Water consumption

Identifiers: NTISQWRR

PB-232 068/7   NTIS Prices: PC A06/MF A01
                              1-4

-------

                                                   Development
C5245G3    fid.

              -11''
  Ia.ntt
  NTISOIOWRT
  PB-243 917/2ST   NTlS Prices:  PC  A02/MF A01
                               1-5

-------
Alternate  Solutions  to  Water  Resource  Development—A Case
Study

Texas A and M Univ., College Station.  Water Resources Inst.

Technical rept.  1  Sep 72-31  Dec 73
AUTHOR: Basco, David R.; Rahman, K. M. A.
C3215C2    Fid:  138, 488*   GRAI7418
May 74   187p*
Rept No: TR-55
Contract: DI-14-31-0001-3938
Project: OWRR-B-141-TEX
Monitor: W74-09661

Abstract:  An effort is made to develop procedural  methodology
for  the  consideration  of   alternative  solutions  for water
resources development in a short period of time  with  a  view
toward  reduction  of  total  costs involved in prefeasibi1ity
studies.  Three techniques  were  developed  to  estimate  the
Investment costs of a reservoir project, a levee project,  and
a basin  conservation reservoir project  in an economic  region.
The  application   of  the  methodologies were  illustrated by a
case study.   The  cost of a reservoir project in the case study
area   determined   by  the  method  developed  was  in excellent
agreement  with   the  Corps  of  Engineers'   estimate   using
conventional  methods.  Selected solutions for water resources
development problems in  the  Navasota  River  watershed  were
analyzed.   The   cost  of  water supply by desalination  in the
service  area  of the proposed Millican reservoir was  computed.
The  investment   costs of the alternatives were compared.  The
multipurpose  reservoir project for flood control,  water supply
and recreation was  found to be the least costly project.

Descriptors:  *Water resources, *Economic development,  *Texas,
Investments,   Multiple purpose reservoirs,  Project planning,
Cost comparison,   Feasibility,  Levees,  Embankments,  Benefit
cost analysis,  Flood control,  Water supply,  Cost estimates,
Desalting,^Navasota River, Bravos  River Basin

Identifiers:  Millican Reservoir(Texas), Alternative water use,
NTISDIOWRR

PB-233  725/1   NTIS Prices:  PC A09/MF A01
                               1-6

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
Commercial  Navigation  on  the  Upper  Mississippi River:  An
Economic Review of Its Development and  Public  Policy  Issues
Affecting Minnesota

Minnesota   Univ.,   Minneapolis,   Water  Resources  Research
Center.*0ffice of Water Research and Technology,   Washington,
D.C. .
AUTHOR:  Christiansen, Rodney W.
C4521A3    Fid: 05C,  13B, 13J,  96B, 85B   GRAI7511
Oct 74   125p
Rept No: WRRC-Bull-75
Contract: DI-14-31-0001-3601
Project: OWRT-B-054-MINN
Monitor: OWRT-B-054-MINN(6)

Abstract:   Inland waterway transport is a significant carrier
of domestic cargo,  accounting for about  14%   of  the  total
traffic.   During  the past decade cargo carried by the inland

          increased by 46%  (62%  when  the  Great  Lakes  are
                  increasing  the  absolute  amount  of freight
                than the average (42%),   the inland waterway's
                 of  total freight traffic has also grown over
                  Also,  development of  the Upper  Mississippi
                major  inland  waterway   has  been  even  more
                Minnesota and the Midwest than for much of the
               nation.   A  transportation  model,   based  on
waterways
excluded).   By
carried greater
relative  share
the past decade
River  into  a
significant for
rest  of  the
competitive   assumptions   and  employing  a  derived  demand
analysiSi is presented.  The model predicts that there will be
an increase in demand for transportation services,  especially
barge services.  The current issues in  commercial  navigation
which  affect  Minnesota  involve a resolution of the conflict
between developmental and environmental values.

Descriptors: *Economic analysis, *Mississippi River, *Waterway
transportation,    *Minnesota,    Economic   models.     Cargo
transportation,  Inland waterways,  Dredging,  Waste disposal,
Policies, Benefit cost analysis, Demand(Economics), Commercial
transportat ion

Identifiers: NTISDIOWRT

PB-239 962/4ST   NTIS Prices: PC A06/MF A01
                             1-7

-------
Economic Base Study of the Mobile-Alabama-Coosa Riven Basin

Alabama Univ.,  University. Bureau of  Business Research
01481C1    Fid: 13B   d7604
dun 67   120p
Contract: PH-86-65-45
Monitor: 18

Abstract: This report presents the results of an Economic Base
Study of the Mobi1e-Alabama-Coosa (MAC) River Drainage Basins.
One  purpose  of  the study was to project the economic growth
and development of the MAC Basin area to 1965, 1980, and 2015,
for development plans of water and related land  resources  to
meet emerging needs. Economic and demographic characteristics,
growth   rates,   and  trends are developed through time-series
analyses and taken into account in  projecting  future  growth
and development patterns  for use in planning activities.

Descriptors: *Water resources,  *Resources management,  *Riven
basin  development,  Mobile-Alabama-Coosa river  basins,    Land
development, Economic factors. Water pollution

Identifiers: NTISEPAO

PB-260 077/3ST   NTIS Prices: PC A06/MF A01
                          1-8

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
An  Economic
for the Upper
CarolIna
              Analysis of the Proposed Water Resources Project
               French  Broad  River  Basin  in  Western  North
                                          Water  Research  and
Georgia   Univ.,    Athens.*0ffice   of
Technology, Washington, O.C.   (153 970)

Doctoral thesis
AUTHOR: Sellers, d.
C4525C2    Fid: 13B, 05C, 488   GRAI7511
1972   313p
Project: OWRT-A-040-GA
Monitor: OWRT-A-040-GA(1)

Abstract:  A procedure is develooed and tested for  evaluating
water resources projects  based on economic, social, legal, and
environmental  considerations. The areas of economic theory and
public  finance  that  apply  to  water  resources investments
supplied the basis for the analysis.   Additional  information
concerning  the environmental aspects were integrated with the
economic and public finance aspects to  develop  a  systematic
process  for evaluation.   The proposed water resources project
for the Upper  French Broad River Basin in North  Carolina  was
completely based on the methodologies that have been developed
up to the present time.

Descriptors:   *Water  resources,   *River  basin development,
•Benefit cost  analysis,  Project planning,  Recreation,   Flood
control,   Social welfare,  Regional planning.  Theses,   Water
pollution control, Economic impact, Assessments,   French Broad
River Basin, North Carolina

Identifiers: NTISDIOWRT

P8-240 563/7ST   NTIS Prices: PC A14/WF A01

-------
An Economic Evaluation of Water Quality Management Systems

Clemson Univ.,  S.C.  Water Resources Research Inst.*0fffee of
Water Research and Technology, Washington, D.C.

Completion rept.
AUTHOR: Macau lay, Hugh H.;  Yandle, T. Bruce Jr
C6201E1    Fid: 138, 05C, 68D*, 96A*   GRAI7609
Oct 75   84p*
Rept No: WRRI-58
Contract: DI-14-31-0001-4041,  DI-14-31-0001-5041
Project: OWRT-A-030-SC
Monitor: OWRT-A-030-SC(2)

Abstract:  There  are  three  general  economic  policies  for
dealing  with  water  pollution,   each  one  with a different
following.  Pollticians and government  administrators  prefer
regulations  to  restrict  the  amount  of waste discharged by
firms. Businessmen prefer government subsidies for cleaning up
their  affluent.   Economists    prefer   charges   on   wastes
discharged,  based on the marginal damage dona.  AH  three ar»
discussed.   Regulations   are   described   as   inefficient^
capricious, and destined to create dissatisfaction on the part
of all parties affected.  Subsidies are even more inefficient
administratively difficult,  and  have  probably  reduced  the
treatment  of  wastes.   Charges  may  result  in  significant
transaction costs but should be the most  efficient  in  waste
treatment  and production of  final output.  But charges should
be levied on all users of water quality,   not  on  mills  and
municipalities  only.   Water   pollution  policies in Germany,
England,   the  Netherlands,    and  France  are  examined  and
evaluated.

Descriptors: *Government policies,  *Water quality management,
*Economic analysis,  East Germany,  Regulations,   Benefit cost
analysis,   Taxes,   Water  pollution,  Policies,  River basin
development, Water pollution abatement,  Foreign policy,  West
Germany,    Great  Britain,   Netherlands,   France,    Grants,
Allocations, Europe, Profits,  Social welfare, Industries

Identifiers:. National government,   *Foreign countries,  *Water
pollution abatement, NTISDICWRT

PB-249 741/OST   NTIS Prices:  PC A05/MF A01

-------

 Effects of Economic Development on Water Resources
 Technical  rept.

 AUTHOR:  Cumoeriand,  John H.;  Herzog,  Henry w.  Jr
 D3155K1     Fid:  13B,  660   GRAI7720
 Aon 77   66p
 Rept No:  TR-40
 Contract:  DI-14-31 -0001-5020
 Project:  OWRT-A-028-MD
 Monitor:  OWRT-A-028-MD( 1 )
effect  the generation of residuals.  Methods were
                                           o                 e
           n n      'duals-   and  to  trace  the flows through
           processes  and   environmental   media.    Specific

outn,f e9P°SS  ^!1dual  coefficients  were derived for the
output of emissions from 92 types of  economic  activity  into
the Chesapeake Bay by 15 major river basins.    aciivitv  '"to
ana-*t     M .neso^ces,   'Industrial wastes,  *Cost
andly;,,,, *water pollution, *Chesapeake Bay,  Economic models

          "'   SSWae
EsimatPs  F                        .     -n
Estimates, Flow charting, Water pollution abatement

Identifiers: NTISDIOWRT


P8-269 096/4ST   NTIS Prices:  PC A04/MF A01
                             i-n

-------
The    Interrelationship
Environmental  Quality in
Interindustry  Analysis
   of    Economic
the Upper Colorado
 Development
River  Basin:
and
 An
Colorado Univ., Boulder.  Dept. of Economics.
Research rept.
AUTHOR: Udis,  Bernard;  Howe,  Charles W.
C2102J2    Fid:  138, 5C,  48B,  96G, 86K
Jul 73   651p
Grant: EDA-OER-351-G-71-8
Monitor: EDA/OER-73-122
                Kreider,
                GRAI7403
      Jan F.
Abstract:   A  set  of compatible models relating the economic
activities of the sub-basins of the Upper Colorado River, both
present and prospective, to air quality and water quantity and
quality resulting from those patterns of economic activity  is
developed.   The  purpose of such a s^t of models is to enable
the planner to test some of the environmental  implications  of
alternative  growth  patterns  for  the  region.   The  report
describes in detail the models which have been  developed  ?,nd
calibrated  for  the  three  upccr  sub-basins (the Upper Main
Stem, the Green, and the San Juan), an area which contains the
origins of the most pressing problems of the basin;  salinity,
shale oil industry future impacts, and the expanded diversions
of water of the Rocky Mountain Eastern Slope.

Descriptors:    *Upper   Colorado   River   basin,   *Economic
development, *Water quality, *Water resources, Economic models
,  Salinity, Air pollution,  San Juan River basin,  Green River
basin,   Industries,   Hydrology,
pollutionT   Water   distribution,
Recreational facilities, Oil shale,
           Regional   planning,  Water
             Atmospheric   diffusion,
           Computer  programs
Identifiers: *Air quality,  EDA
COM-73-11970/3   NTIS Prices: PC E16/MF A01

-------

A Methodology for Assessment of Water Resources Development: A
Competitive  Evaluation  Model for Water Resources Development
Planning

Oklahoma Water Resources Research Inst., Stillwater.

Completion rept.
AUTHOR: Reid, George w.; Law, Silas S. Y.
C1984D3    Fid: 13B, 48B*   GRAI7401
Jul 73   201p*
Contract: 01-14-31-0001-3836
Project: OWRR-A-036-OKLA
Monitor: OWRR-A-034-OKLA(1)

Abstract: An effective evaluation methodology for assisting in
water resources development planning  is developed. A new model

was contemplated for solving two principal  problems associated
with the present  practices  of  water  resources  development
planning  -   the  considering  of  individual  development as
isolated entity and the using of the benefit and cost ratio as
the only analysis in the evaluation process.   The  model  was
developed by using game theory concepts. The principal tactics
employed  in  the  model are the competitive measuring between
bensfit categories  and  the  competitive  evaluation  of  the
development  objectives.   The  procedures  used  in the model
enables the  identifying of the following:  the overall  system
of  water  resources  development as well as the individual or
local  development,   the  relationship  and   priorities   of
developments   in  different  locations  and  between  various
purposes of development.  The model  is also able to  recognize
the  competitive  nature of water resources development and to
augment some new measurements. The model as a whole provides a
new approach for summarizing a large number  of  data  into  a
simple  and  meaningful  form in order to formulate systematic
recommendations  for  the  decision-maker.    (Modified  author
abstract)

Descriptors: (*River basin development,  Mathematical models),
(*Water resources,  Project planning),  Evaluation,  Game theory,
Benefit cost analysis,  Statistical   data,    Decision  making,
Regional planning,   Systems analysis,   Measurement,   Heuristic
methods, Cost effectiveness, Methodology

Identifiers: OWRR

PB-224 825/0   NTIS Prices:  PC A10/MF A01
                             1-13

-------
People and the Sound. An Economic Perspective

New  England River Basins Commission,  Boston,  Mass. *Econom1c
Research Service,  Broomal I ,   Pa.*Bureau of Economic Analysis,
Washington, O.C.
Final rept
C54G5F4
Aug 75
Rept No:
Monitor:
Report
           Fid: 13B, 05C, 91H,
         86p
         LISS-13
         18
        on  Long  Island Sound
with Economic Research Service
Economic Analysis, Washington,
Paper  copy  also  available
233-SET, PCS61.00.
                               488, 96A   GRAI7525
                               Study.  Prepared in cooperation
                              ,  Sroomall,  Pa.,  and Bureau of
                               D.C.
                              in  set  of 14 reports as P8-245
Abstract:  The report examines the  economic  and  demographic
trends  in the Lcng Island Sound region,  with data for use as
the basis of all  projections macJa in  the  Long  Island  Sound
Study.   It  is  part of the final report of the Study,  whicn
outlines a strategy for securing the balanced conservation and
development  of  natural  resources  of  the  Sound  and   its
shoreline in both New York and Connecticut.  The plan for Long
Island Sound is an increment of the New England  River  Basins
Commission comprehensive,  coordinated joint plan for the water
and  related land resources of its region,   which includes New
England and the New York portions of Long Island Sound.

Descriptors: *Regional planning, *Matural resources, 'Economic
development, *Long Island Sound, Demography,  Land use,  Water
resources,    Land   development,    Industries,   Employment,
Conservation,  Management,  New York, Connecticut

Identlfjers: NTISNERBC. NTISCOMBSA, NTISAGERS

PB-245 246/4ST   NT IS Prices: PC A05/MF A01
                          1-14

-------

 Plan   for   Development  of  the  Land  and Water  Resources of  the
 Southeast  River  Basins. Appendix 9.  Economics

 United States Study Commission  Southeast River Basins  Atlanta
 C-a    (410288)

 Final  rept.
 D3111I2     Fid:  138, 488, 91H   GRAI7720
 1963   24ip
 monitor: 18
 Original contains color plates: All  DOC and NTIS reproductions
 will  be   in black and white.   Appendix 9 to AO-A041 835.   See
 also  Appsndix 10 and 11, AO-A041 850.

 Abstract:   This  Appendix provides a  listing and review of   the
 economic    studies   and    analyses   made   in   preparing  a
 comprehensive,   integrated  plan of development of the land  and
 water resources  of the Southeast River Basins area. Throughout
 this  Reoort  the  term  economic  is  used in its broad sense
 covering many economic,  social and  institutional  conditions
 and adjustments. Part One sets  forth the conceptual framework,
 objectives,   controlling   assumptions,   criteria,  and study
 guidelines.  Part  Two  summarizes   and  describes  the  basic
 studies  carried  out to meet the plan objectives.  Part Three
 contains the Economic  Framework  or  general   guidelines   for
 planning.  Some of these guidelines  had their origin in recent
 national studies,  the results of which were  adopted  by   the
 Commission  as  general  guides  for regional  planning.   Other
 guidelines were developed by the staff from the basic studies.
 Part  Four presents  the  principles  and  procedures  used  in
 making  economic  evaluation studies of programs and projects.
 Part  Five discusses cost sharing and  financing  as  important
 aspects of the implementation of the resource plan.

 Descriptors: *Water resources, *8asins(Geographic),  *Economic
analysis,-North Carolina,    South Carolina,   Georgia,  Florida,
 Alabama,    Planning,    Demography,    Agriculture,   Employment,
 Commerce, Cost analysis

 Identifiers: River Basin development, NTISDODXA

 AD-A041 844/2ST   NTIS Prices: PC A11/MF A01
                              1-15

-------
The Powder River Basin Economic Simulation Model:  A Technical
Report and Supplement to the Technical Report

Wyoming Univ., Laramie.   Water Resources Research lnst.*0ffice
of Water Research and Technology, Washington, D.C.

Completion rept.
AUTHOR: Carlson, John F.; Phillips, Clynn
E2102H1    Fid: 5C, 138, 91J   GRAI7820

Aug 77   196p
Contract: DI-14-31-0001-5237
Project: CWRT-C-6311(5237)
Monitor: OWRT-C-6311(5237)(1)

Abstract1     The    development    and   application   of   a
continuous-growth   economic    simulation    model    to    a
discrete-growth economy are described.  The model developed is
a further adaptation of the North Platte River Basin  Economic
Simulation Model (1976) to Wyoming's Powder River Basin, which
includes five Wyoming counties.  The model is employment-based
and simulates economic activity in seven sectors:  population,
employment, water demand, land use, income,  agriculture,  and
housing.  All major economic variables contained  in the  model
are  expressed  in  terms  of functions relating dependent and
inaependent  variables,   thus  allowing  virtually  unlimited
experimentation with various functional forms.

Descriptors:   *Powder River basin,  *Economic models,  *River
basin development, Economic analysis, Populations, Employment,
Water consumption, Land use, Income, Water resources. Manpower
,  Computerized simulation,   Agriculture,   Housing  studies,
Wyoming

Identifiers: NTISDIOWRT

PB-282 562/8ST   NTIS Prices: PC A09/MF A01
                              1-16

-------
     I
     I
    I
    I
    I
    I
   I
   I
   I
   I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
Research  on  Water Resources Evaluation Methodology'•  A River
Basin Economic and Financial Post-Audit

Little (Arthur D.),  Inc.,  Cambridge,  Mass."Office of  Water
Research and Technology, Washington, D.C.   (208 850)

Final rept.
AUTHOR: Wilkinson, vJohn M.
C4662I2    Fid: 138, 05C, 488, 96A   GRAI7513
31 Mar 75   203p
Contract: DI-14-31-0001-4228
Project: OWRT-C-5126(4228)
Monitor: OWRT-C-5126(4228)(1)

Abstract: Benefit-cost analysis has long been relied upon as a

tool  for planning  and  justifying river-basin programs.  Almost
no  record  is kept  of actual benefit accruals to  compare  with
planning   expectations.   This  postaudit  of  the  Pick-Sloan
Missouri Basin  Program   attempted  to  quantify  the  30-year
performance of multipurpose programs  in dollar terms.  Applying
current  evaluation  Principles  and  Standards  of  the Water
Resources  Council  on an  ex-post basis,  the objective  *as   to
determine  how much physical and dollar realities have  differed,
frcm  original plans, why  they have differed,  and what are  the
implications for  future  planning.  Because benefit  estimating
procedures remain so  imperfect,  a wide range of values could
be  quantified;  however,   it appears  that  flood  control   and
electric   power  program performance  far exceeded plan,  while
that  for irrigation and  navigation programs  fell far short   of
plan.  Benefits could be  double or half most of those estimated
in  this post-audit, depending on value assumptions.

Descriptors:    *Water    resources,    *Economic  development,
*Missouri  River,  Benefit  ccst analysis, Financing,  Hydrology,
Flood control, Irrigation,  Recreation,  Wildlife,  Navigation,
Water supply, Hydroelectric power generation, Fishes

Identifiers: NTISDIOWRT

PB-241 061/1ST   NTIS  Prices: PC A10/MF A01
                            1-17

-------
Subsidies,   Capital  Formation,    and  Technological  Change:
Municipal Wastewater Treatment Facilities. Volume 1

Charles River Associates,  Inc.,    Cambridge,   Mass.*National
Bureau of Standards, Washington,  D.C.  Experimental  Technology
Incentives Progr-am.   (402 974)

Final rept.
E2673H4    Fid: 5C, 5A,  138,  96A*, 70F*, 680*   GRAI7825
dul 77   150p*
Rept No: CRA-302.03
Contract: NBS-6-35744
Monitor: NBS-GCR-ETIP-78-40
_See also Volume 2, PB-28S 289._
Also available in set of 8 reports PC E19, PB-285 287-SET.
Abstract:  The study evaluates
grants  for  the  improvement
waterways.  The  analysis  is
important  program  in  this
assist in the construction of
as called for  in  the  1972
comparison with this program's annual  funding of S5
$6  billion,   other  programs  in  this  area  are
faci1i t ies
supplemented   by
states. The grant
legislation which
control  poli cy
                               the economic impact of  federal
                               of  the quality of the nation's
                               confined  to  the  single  most
                              area,   namely federal  grants to
                              municipal waste treatment plants
                              Water  Quality  Amendments.    By
                                                    bi11 ion to
                                                     vi rtual1y
insignificant.  The program provides  municipalities  with  75
percent  of  the  costs  of  constructing wastewater treatment
            which  meet  EPA  approval   and   it   is   often
                   additional  construction  grants  from  the
                  program is part of the broad body of federal
                  sets  forth  the  nation's  water  pollution
         ,— .-, -    This  legislation  provides  a  system  for
defining and enforcing effluent standards  pertaining  to  all
point  source  dischargers.   Grants  are  available  only  to
municipal dischargers except for an  implicit,   but  smaller,
subsidy  to  industries  who  tie  into municipal systems.  Of
particular concern are the effects of the program both in  the
production  of  municipal  waste  treatment and on the rate of
technological  change in the industry.  Attention is also given
to  the  program's  impact  on  the  rate  of  growth in waste
treatment  plant  construction  and  on   its   distributional
implicatTons.

Descriptors:   *Federal assistance programs,  *Economic impact,
*Sewage treatment, Grants, Municipalities,   Economic analysis,'
Economic development, Capital, Government policies, Incentives
,    Construction,   Water quality,  Legislation,  Regulations,
Waterways(Watercourses),  Water supply, Water resources

Identifiers:  technological change, technological development
,   Economic growth,  *Sewage treatment  plants,   Innovations,
*Water pollution control, NTISCOMN8S

PB-285 288/7ST   NTIS Prices! PC A07/MF A01
                            1-18

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
The  Willamette Basin Comprehensive Study of Water and Related
Land Resources. Appendix C. Economic Base

Pacific Northwest River Basins Commission Vancouver  Wash    (
410072)
0198413    Fid: 13B, 8H, 483, 68D, 91H   GRAI7711
1969   285p
Moni tor: 18
Original contains coior plates:  AH DDC reproductions will be
in black and white.  Appendix C  to  AD-A036  745.   See  also
Appendix 0, AD-A03S 749.

Abstract:   This is a specialized study designed to serve as a
guide  to  water  and  related  land   resources   development
planning. An expanding economy requires more resources or more
intensive  resource  utilization.   Aa  demands  for resources
increase,  the increase in their supply can often be  attained
only  by  developing  more  costly  sources  or  by  utilizing
resources more intensively.  In particular,  future demand for
water looms large. Assuring that demands for resources will be
satisfied   in   the   best   manner   requires  comprehensive

development plans.  These plans should in turn be based on the
Character and growth of the basin's economy.  The objective of
the  Economic  Base  Study   is  to  provide  the   basis   for
determining  the  scale,   sequence,   and timing of water and
related  land resources development.  These determinations  are
based  on  estimates  of  future  economic activity within the
basin and tne characteristics and size of its population.   In
estimating  the  basin's  future economic activity,  regional,
national,   and  foreign  trade  in  goods  and  services  are
recognized.   Exports  of  basin products enhance the economic
growth of the basin. The economic parameters projected in this
study may be used in determining the  need  for  each  of  the
resource  planning  oojectives.   Useful   economic  parameters
include  (1) population and its characteristics—age, sex,  and
per  capita  income—for  estimates of visitor-day use in fish
and wildlife, and recreation studies; (2) output of industries
uaing large quantities of water and power,  for  estimates  of
municipal and industrial water and power requirements; and (3)
changes  in urban, industrial, and agricultural  development.

Descriptors:   *Water  resources,   *Env1ronmental management,
*Economic  analysis,   *Water  pollution  abatement,   Rivers,
8asins{Geogfaphic),   Land use,  Planning,  Population,  Urban
areas,   Rural  areas,   Agriculture,   Industrial  production,
Recreation,   Navigation,  Irrigation systems,   Flood control,
Oregon

Identifiers:  *Wi1lamette River Basin,  *Economic feasibility,
•Water resources development, NTISOOOXA

AO-A036 748/2ST   NTIS Prices: PC A13/MF A01
                             1-19

-------
 1.3  Alphabetical  Listing of Socio-Political  Analysis  Abstracts

 1.    An Analytical  Interdisciplinary Evaluation of the Utilization of the
      Water Resources of the Rio Grande in New Mexico:   Socorro Region.

 2.    Basin Governance.

 3.    Comprehensive Basin Study.  Red River Below Denison Dam,  Arkansas,
      Louisiana, Oklahoma, and Texas.  Volume 3.  Appendix V.

 4.    An Economic Study of Voter Attitudes Toward Different Proposals
      for the Use of an Undeveloped Island, Sears Island, Maine.

 5.    Improvement of Planning for Post-Development Water Resource Management:
      A Study of the Weber Basin Project.

 6.    Improvements Needed by the Water Resources Council and River Basin
      Commissions to Achieve the Objectives of the Water Resources Planning
      Act of 1965.

 7.    Issues and Opinions on the Social Effects of Water Allocation for
      Coal Development in the Yellowstone  River Drainage.

 8.    Laws Relating to Industrial and Agricultural Activities.

 9.    Legal-Political History of Water Resource Development in  the Upper
      Colorado River Basin, Part I.  Summary of the Legislative History
      of the Colorado River Storage Project.  Part II.   The Politics of
      Water Resource Development in the Upper Colorado  River Basin.

10.    Lower Sheyenne River Basin, Water, Land, People.

11.    Multiobjective Interagency Study of  the Bear River Basin  Water and
      Related Land Resources.  (Utah).

12.    People and the Sound.  Marine Transportation Planning Report.

13.    Plan of Study Subproject Report for  a Case Study  of a Federal
      Expenditure on a Water and Related Land Resource  Project, Boise
      Project, Idaho and Oregon.

14.    Problem Identification and Ranking - An Assessment of a River Basin
      Planning Process.

15.    Proceedings of the Conference on Interdisciplinary Analysis of Water
      Resource Systems Held at Colorado University, Boulder, Colorado,
      on June 19-22, 1973.

16.    Report of Testing Special Task Force Evaluation Procedures Water
      Resource Council for Poteau River Watershed, Scott County, Arkansas
      and LeFlore County, Oklahoma.
                                    i-zn

-------
 I
 I
            117.   Rocky Mountain  Environmental  Research.  Quest  for a  Future.   Problems
                 and  Research  Priorities  in  the  Rocky Mountain  Region.
            118.   Water Supply  and  Wastewater in  Coastal Areas:   Proceedings of Southeastern
                 Conference  Held on  April  2-4, 1975.
            19.   The  Winooski  Workshops:   An Assessment of  Specified  Workshop  Techniques
 I              for  Stimulating and Improving Public Involvement in  Water Resources.
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
•                                            1-21

-------
1.4  Socio-Political  Analysis Abstracts
                                  1-22

-------
 I

I
I
I
I
                         An  Analytical Interdisciolinary Evaluation of the Utilization
                         of the Water Resources  of  the  Rio  Grande  in  New  Mexico:
                         Socorro Region
                         New  Mexico  State
                         Research Inst.

                         Partial technical
                         AUTHOR: lansford,
                         G. Jr; Brutsaert,
Univ.
                             University Park.  Water Resources
                  completion rept.
                  Robert R.; Ben-David,
                  Wi11i am; Creel, Bobby
                           GRAI7411
                    Shaul
                    J.
Gebhard, Thomas
                         C2721G3    Fid: 138, 488
                         Dec 73   107p
                         Rept No: WRRI-023
                         Project: OWRR-A-045-fJMEX
                         Monitor: OWPR-A-045-NMEX(4)

                         Abstract: An interdisciplinary approach to the solution of the
                         water resource problems of the Soccrro Region  in  New  Mexico
                         was  centered  around  a  socio-economic  model,  developed to
                         represent the New Mexico economy, with special emphasis placed
                         upon the Rio Grande region.  Inputs   into  the  socio-economic
                         model   were  obtained  from  separata  studies  covering  the
                         hydro 1051ca1,  agricultural,  mur.icioal,  and  industrial areas.
                         Three sets of alternatives were considered: (1) growth without
                         a  water  constraint;   (2)   growth,   with  a  surface-water
                         constraint; (3)  growth,  with both surface-  and ground-water
                         constraints. (Modified author abstract)
Descriptors: *New Mexico, *Water resources,
River basin dovol opnient,   Rio Grande River>,
Ground waters,  Utilization

Identifiers: OWRR

PB-230 815/7   NTIS Prices: PC A06/MF A01
                         *Economic
                          Surface
        model 3,
        waters,

-------
Basin Governance

Cornell Univ.  Agricultural  Experiment Station,  Ithaca,  N.Y.
Dept.   of  Agricultural   Economics.*Utah  Center  for   Water
Resources Research, Logan.
AUTHOR: Allee, David J.;  Caoener,  Harold R.;  Andrews, Wade H.
C7202B4    Fid: 13B, 8H,  5K,  5C, 48B, 48G, 92C   GRA17621
Dec 75   29p
Rept No: Staff Paper-75-25
Monitor: OWRT-B-136-UTAH(1)
Prepared  in  cooperation with Utah Center for Water Resources
Research,   Logan,   Contract   01-14-31-0001-5141,    Project
OWRT-B-136-UTAH.

Abstract: The report is the result of three workshop sessions.
The  complex  organizational   problems  of  regional and river
basin management call for a major  integrated effort of several
social science disciplines.   An approach to this  research   is
recommended.   Requirements of social science research on this
problem are:  first,  support of an  interdisciplinary  social
science  research  team  through  the  necessary phases of the
broad problem.  The mapping and inventorying  of  river  basin
management and organization is the first stage of this worK. A
second  requirement is to support the work through an adequate
period of time to complete the stages necessary.

Descriptors:  *River basin development,   *Regional  planning,
*Sosioeconomic  status,   Research  management,  Water quality
management, Organizations, Social effect, Budgeting, Political
objectives. Cost control, Economic analysis
Identifiers:   institutional   framework,
relationships, NTISOIOWRT

PB-255 099/4ST   NTIS Prices! PC A03/MF A01
Intergovernmental
                             1-24

-------
 I
 I
 I
I
 I
 I
 I
I
 I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
Comprehensive  Basin  Study.   Red  River  Below  Denison Dam,
Arkansas, Louisiana, Oklahoma, and Texas. Volume 3. Appendix V

Red River Basin Coordinating  Committee  New  Orleans  La    (
410089)
D1985A1    Fid: 13B, 8H,  48B, 680, 48G   GRAI7711
Jun 68   260p
Monitor: 18
Appendix to report dated Jun 68, AD-A036 742.  See also Volume
4,  Apoendices 6 and 7,  AO-A036 751.  Original contains color
plates; All ODC reproductions will be in black and white.

Abstract:  The purposes of this document is to:  (1)  Identify
water and related land  resource  problems;   (2)   prepare  a
potential plan for water and related land resource development
that  could be accomplished undsr USDA programs;  (3)  prepare
agricultural  and forestry data for use of cooperating agencies
in planning water and related resource  projects  under  their
programs; and (4) compile engineering,  economic,  and related
data that local organizations could use for  developing  water
and related land resources.

Descriptors:  *Water resources, *Rivers,  *Watersheds, *Land use
,  *Water supplies, Economic analysis,  Management planning and
control,  Basins(Geographic),  Agriculture,   Forestry,   Soil
erosion, Population, Employment

Identifiers:  *Red River Basin, Arkansas, Louisiana,  Oklahoma,
Texas,   *Water  resources  development,   *Land  development,
NTISDODXA

AD-A036 750/8ST   NTIS Prices: PC A12/MF A01
I
                                                     1-25

-------
An   Economic   Study  of  Voter  Attitudes  Toward  Different
Proposals for the Use of an Undeveloped Island,  Sears Island,
Maine

Massachusetts Agricultural  Experiment Station, Amherst.
AUTHOR: Seekins, Milton 0.; Storey, David A.
£267304    Fid: 13B, 488, 91H   GRAI7825
May 77   80p
Rept No: BULL-651
Monitor: 18
Library of Congress Catalog Card no. 78-622501.

Abstract:   The  study  deals with voters'   perceptions of the
impacts of various developmental alternatives for a case study
tract of coastal wildland at one  particular   point  in  time,
their  resulting  attitudes  toward the alternatives,  and the
dollar valuations associated with those attitudes.  An attempt
is  made  to  evaluate  relationships  between  socio-economic
characteristics of individuals and the above  measures.   Thus,
the  purpose  is to try to explain variations in attitudes and
valuations by variations in population characteristics,  as an
aid to the planning process in other times and other places.

Descriptors!   *Land  use,    *Coastal  zone management,  *Land
development,  Attitudes,  Socioeconomic status,  Sears Island,
Water resources, Penobscot Bay, Maine

Identifiers:     *Wildlands,     Searsport(Maine),    Stockton
Springs(Maine),    Waldo   County(Maine),     Case    studies.
Alternatives, NTISSLLC

P8-285 270/5ST   NTIS Prices: PC A05/MF A01
                               1-26

-------
 I
 I
 I
 i
 I
 ft
 I
 8
 I
 I
 1
 i
I
i
                      Improvement  of   Planning   for  Post-Development Water Resource
                      Management: A Study of  the  Weber  Basin  Project
                                                      for Social Science
                                                      Water  Research  and
 Research on
 Technology,
Utah State Univ., Logan. Inst.
Natural  Resources.*0ffice  of
Washington, D.CO-
AUTHOR: Madsen, Gary E.; Andrews, Wade H.
02515E4    Fid: 138, 5K, 48B, 92C   GRAI7714
Sep 76   98p
Rept No: Research Mono-6
Contract: DI-14-31-0001-5212
Project: OWRT-C-6092(5212)
                     Monitor: OWRT-C-6092(5212)(1)

                     Abstract: The objectives of  the studies were to:  (1)   Identify
                     present  management  problems  in   the  Weber Basin Project of
                     Utah;   (2)   identify whether the problems are related  to  the
                     planning  process  so  that  relationships between planning and
                     management can be  identified;  (3)    identify  recommendations
                     from    present  management   personnel  concerning  changes  in
                     planning which might help  alleviate management  problems  with
                     future  projects,   as  wel!  as  recommendations  for present
                     solutions to problems; (4)  identify theoretical elements which
                     can be  applied to  future planning.  Present management  problems
                     were  being  experienced   primarily   in  two   areas,    urban
                     pressurized  irrigation systems (where the non-treated  water Is
                     used  for  residential  lawns,   gardens and shrubs),  and the
                     recreation component of the  project.  Several  recommendations
                     for future water resources planning resulted.
                     Descriptors:  *Water resources,  *Social effect,
                     development,  Project planning,  Recommendations,
                     Demand(Economics),   Water  supply.  Recreation,
                     Attitudes, Environmental  impacts, Utah

                     Identifiers':  *Water management (Administrat i ve),
                     project, Water demand, NTISOIOWRT

                     PB-266 009/OST    NTIS Prices:  PC A05/MF A01
*River basin
 Irrigat ion,
Urban areas,
Weber  Basin
t
I
i
                                                  U?7

-------
Improvements  Needed  by the Water
Basin Commissions to  Achieve  the
Resources Planning Act of 1965
                                   Resources Council  and River
                                    Objectives  of  the  Water
                                                 Community and
General  Accounting  Office,  Washington,   D.C.
Economic Development Oiv.
E0172F4    Fid: 13B, 8H,  488*,  48G   GRAI7802
31 Oct 77   17p*
Rept No: CED-78-1
Monitor: 18

Abstract*.  The report reviews selected activities of the Water
Resources  Council and river basin commissions to assess their
progress in implementing  the Water Resources Planning  Act  of
1965. The study concentrates on the Council's responsibilities
to  review  o'ans submitted by  river basin commissions.  These
responsibilities are (1)  to determine both the adequacy of the
plans and their ability to contribute to national water  needs
and  (2)   to  make  recommendations  to  the  President,  for
transmittal to the Congress,  about Fedaral  projects  and  new
Federal  policies  and  programs.    The  study states that the
Council and the river basin commissions have made only limited
progress in achieving these  responsibilities  and  that  they
need  to  further  define  and  implement (1)  the planning and
coordination  goals  of  the  Council  and  the  river   basin
commissions, (2) the means for  accomplishing these goals,  and
(3) the role of the Council and the fiver  basin commissions in
attaining these goals.
Descriptors:  *River  basin  development
Organizations,      Government    policies.
Objectives,   Water conservation,
development,   National   government,   State government,  Loca
            Commerce, Improvement, Research projects
                                            *Water  resources,
                                              Recommendations,
                                  Economic cevelopment,    Land
government,

I dent i f iers~:
NTISGAO
             Water needs,  Water Resource Planning Act of 1965,
PB-273 552/OST   NTIS Prices:  PC A02/MF A01
                               1-28

-------
I
I
I
1
I
I
I
I
I
i
i
i
i
i
i
Issues  and Opinions on the Social Effects of Water A! location
for Coal Development in the Yellowstone River Drainage
Montana  State
Center ,*0ffi ce
D.C.
                Univ.,   Bozeman.   Water  Resources  Research
                of Water Research and Technology,  Washington,
Completion rept .
AUTHOR: Faulkner, Lee G.
D1941H4    Fid: 13B, 8H , 48G, 43F, 68   GRAI7710
Jul 76   187p
Rept No: MUvJWRRC-78
Project: OWRT-C~S303(5230)
Monitor: OWRT-C-6303(5230) (1 )

Abstract:  The results of this study define  issues  of  major
concern to decision makers,  water users,  and residents of the
Yellowstone River drainage region. These issues revolve around
the possible effects of allocation of  water  from  the  study
area  to  the  coal  development  industry.   Water use issues
include potential impacts on water quantity,  in-stream  flow,
water  quality,  and groundwater,  water needs of reclamation,
major water  development  and  water  rights.   Social  Issues
include rapid population growth,  lifestyle changes,  economic
impacts,  impacts on the Indian reservations,  loss  of  local
control  and increases in crime.  Policy questions explored in
the study  include  attitudes  toward  the  handling  of  coal
development   issues   and  information  by  state  and  local
authorities,  levels of coal development,  and alternate means
of  shipping coal.  Implications for policy are drawn from the
results of the residents' survey.

Descriptors: *Water consumption, *Water supply,  *Coal mining,
•Yellowstone   River   Basin,    Availability,    Agriculture,
Industrial water, Water quality management,  Policies,  Social
effect, Attitude surveys, Public opinion, Reservoirs, Economic
impact, American Indians, Crimes, Population growth,  Montana,
Wyoming

Identifiers: Environmental protection, NTISDIOWRT

PB-263 484/SST   NTIS Prices: PC A09/MF AOt
i
i
                                                     1-29

-------
Laws Relating to Industrial and Agricultural Activities

Mississippi-Alabama  Sea  Grant  Consortium,   Ocean  Springs,
Miss.*Mississippi Univ.,   University.   Law  Center.*Nationa1
Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration, Rockville, Md.  Office
of Sea Grant.

Preliminary draft.
C44448!    Fid:  050, 05C, 138, 920, 96, 48B, 36M   GRAI7510
1973   49p
Rept No: MASGP-74-035
Monitor: NQAA-75021811
Prepared by Mississippi Univ., University. Law Center.

Abstract:  The volume is one of ten representing a compilation
of  Mississippi   laws  which most significantly affect the use
and development  of   the  state's  marine  and  coastal  zones.
Various  state,    county,  and local agencies are charged with
implementing a policy of balanced economic development between
agriculture  and  industry.   The  Mississippi  Department  Of
Agriculture  nas  general supervision over all agriculture and
agricultural commodities within the state. Management of water
resources encompasses a wide area  of  activities.   Extensive
legal  citations  are presented.

Descriptors:    *Law(Jurisprudence),   *Economic  development,
*Coasts, *Mississippi,   Administrative law,  Industries,  Land
use,   Agriculture,   Public  law,   Water resources,   Project
planning, Government, Land acquisition

Identifiers: Sea Grant  program, NTISCOiV.NQA

COM-75-10326/7ST   NTIS Prices: PC A03/IWF A01

-------
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
Legal-Political  History  of Water Resource Development in the
Upper Colorado River Basin. Part I. Summary of the Legislative
History of the Colorado River Storage Project.  Part II.   The
Legal-Political  History  of Water Resource Development
Upper Colorado River Basin. Part I. Summary of the Legi
History of the Colorado River Storage Project.  Part II.   The
Politics  of  Water Resource Development in the Upper Colorado
Politics
River Basin
Lake Powell Research Project, Los Angeles,  Cal i f .**Cal i fornia
Univ.,  Los Angeles. *National Science Foundation,  Washington,
D.C. Research Applied to National Needs.
AUTHOR: Weatherford. Gary D.; Nichols, Phillip; Mann, Dean E.
           Fid: 13B, 50, 488, 92D   GRAI7706
         62p
         Bui 1-4
Monitor: NSF/RA/E-74-384
Prepared by California Univ.
D1344G3
Sep 74
Rept No:
                              Los Angeles.
                                                           the
Abstract:  This study is in two parts.  Part I chronicles
dominant  events  of  the  legislative history of the Colorado
River Storage Project Act of 1956.  The  major  political  and
                  emanating from the Colorado River Compact of
                   in the 1956 Act are  identified.   Part  II
approaches  these  historical   events  analytically  from  the
persoective  of  political   science.    The   persistence
distributive politics,  in the face of increasing pressure
legal  decisions
1922 and result ing
a more 'regulator'  mode of deci sion-maMng,  is discussed
                                                            of
                                                           for
                                                            in
the  context  of  some  of  the current problems such as water
quality of the river.  Also,   several  unresolved  issues  of
public policy concerning Colorado River management are posed.

Descriptors: *Water resources,  *Legislat ion,   *Colorado River
Basin, History,  Law(Jurisprudence),   Political science,  Land
use,   Decision  making.   Policies,    Water rights,  Economic
development, Lake Powell,  Utah
Identifiers:  Colorado River Storage Act of 1956,
research project, NTISNSFRA

P8-261 674/6ST   NTIS Prices: PC A04/MF A01
                                                   Lake Powel1
                                                    1-31

-------
Lower Sheyenne Riven Basin, Water, Land, People

Month  Dakota Water Resources Research Inst.  Fargo.*0ffice of
Water Research and Technology, Washington,  D.C.  North Dakota
Agricultural  Experiment Station,  Fargo.*Sheyenne River Basin
Research Team, N. Dak.
Completion rept.
AUTHOR: Barker, William T,
              Nelson, Wi11iam C.
C5871A1    Fid:  13B, 63D, 91H   GRAI7605
Sep 74   121p
Rept No: W1-222-005-75
Contract: 01-14-31-0001-4116
Project: OWRT-B-029-NDAK
Monitor! OWRT-B-029-NOAK(1)
Also pub.  as North Dakota  Agricultural  Experiment  Station,
Fargo,  Research rept.  no.   55.  Prepared in cooperation with
Sheyenne River Basin Research Team, N. Dsk.

Abstract:  Rivers in the Northern Great  Plains  are  carrying
increasing  pollutant  concentrations  as the density of human
and livestock populations and intensity  of   land  cultivation
increase.   The  major  emphasis  of  this  muIti-disciplinary
project is to quantitatively determine the relationships among
land,  people, and wats-r Quality; and to evaluate th% impact of
alternative means to increase water quality.  Activities during
the first year of the project included:  (1)   Mapping  of  the
land  use  of  the  complete  basin;  (2)  mapping the surface
geology of the upper portion  of  the  basin;   (3)   periodic
testing  of  the  river  water for 22
mapping  of  population  densities;
socioeconomic   characteristics   of
statistical analysis  of  the  relationshio   among  the  water
quality  indicators  and  basin  descriptors.   Water  quality
indicators   frequently   exceeded    established    pollution
standards.  The variation in water quality was related to flow
rates,   temperature,   density   of   human    and   livestock
populations, and the intensity of land cultivation.

Descriptors:   *Land  use,   *Water pollution,  *Sheyenne River
Basin,   Water  quality,   Livestock,   Agricultural   wastes,
Geological   surveys,   Mapping,   Concentration(Composition),
Population(Statistics), Social welfare,  Economic development,
Statistical  analysis.  Standards,  Mathematical models,  Flow
rate.  Stream flow, Hydrogeology, North Dakota
                        quality indicators;   (4)
                         (5)    description    of
                         tha   basin;   and   (6)
Identi flers:
NTISDIOWRT
Northern  Great  Plains  Region(United  States)
PB-248 068/9ST   NTIS Prices: PC A06/MF A01
                                1-32

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
 I
 1
1
I
I
I
Multiobjective Interagency Study of the Bear River Basin Water
and Related Land Resources. (Utah)

Utah Div. of  Water Resources,  Salt Lake City.

Comprehensive water Planning Program.
F0071D1    Fid: 138, 488, 68D, 91H   GRAI7901
Dec 76   169p
Monitor: 18

Abstract:   This study included the formulation and evaluation

of plans for use and development of  water  and  related  land
resources. This report includes an inventory of basic resource
data  and projected population and associated needs over time,
with  a  National  Economic  Development  Plan,   a   regional
development plan, and an environmental quality plan.

Descriptors:  *Land use,  *Water resources,  *Bear River Basin,
Inventories,   Populations,   Economic  development,   Regional
planning,    Climatology,   Wildlife,   Recreation,   Erosion,
Geomorohology,  Irrigation,  Local government,   Environmental
impacts,  Pernography,  Mineral deposits,  Constraints,  Social
effect, Benefit cost analysis, Evaluation

Identifiers:  NTISSLLC

PB-286 282/9ST   NTIS Prices:  PC A08/MF A01
                                                    1  oo

-------
People and the Sound.  Marine Transportation Planning Report

New  England River Basins Commission,  Boston,  Mass.*Maritime
Administration,  Washington, D.C.*Department of Transportation,
Washington,  O.C.*Corps of Engineers,   Waltham,   Mass.   New
England Div.
Final rept.
C5465E3
Aug 75
Rept No:
Moni tor:
Report
           Fid!  130, 05C, 8SB, 91H, 96A, 86L   GRAI7525
         S9p
         LISS-08
         18
        on  Long  Island Sound Stuay.  Prepared
with Maritime Administration, Washington, O.C.,
of Transportation,  Washington.  O.C.  Prepared
Engineers, Waltham, Mass. New England Div.
              in cooperation
              and Department
               by  Corps  of
Paper  copy  also  available
233-SET, PCS61.00.
                              1 n
set  of 14 reports as PB-245
Abstract:    A   planning   report   describes   the    marine
transportation  element  of  the  Long  Island  Sound regional
study.   It is part of the final report of  the  study,   which
outlines a strategy for securing the balanced conservation and
development   of  natural  resources  of  the  Sound  and  its
shoreline in both New York and Connecticut.   The plan for Long
Island   Sound  is an increment of the New England River Basins
Cotr.mission comprehensive, coordinated joint  plan for the water
and related land resources of  its region,  which includes  New
England  and the New York portions of Long Island Sound.

Descriptors: *Marine transportation, *Regional planning, *Long
Island Sound, Ports, Harbors, Conservation,  Development, Water
resources, New England, New YorX,  Land development,  Economic
forecasting,  Problem solving,  Evaluation,    Recommendations,
Cargo transportation, Commerce

Identifiers: NriSNERSC, NTISDOTG, NTISCOMMA

PB^-245 241/5ST   NTlS Prices: PC A05/MF A01
                              1-34

-------
I
I
1
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
1
I
I
I
Plan  of Study Subproject Report for a Case Study of a Federal
Expenditure on a Water  and  Related  Land  Resource  Project,
Boise Project, Idaho and Oregon

Idaho Univ., Moscow.  Water Resources Research Inst.*0ffice of
Water Research and Technology, Washington, D.C.

Completion rept.
AUTHOR: Haas, Wayne T.; Schermerhorn, Richard
 C5872E2     Fid:  13B,  08H,  05C,  488,  48G,  96    GRAI7605
 dun  74    47p
 Project:  OWRT-C-4202(9061)
 Monitor:  OWRT-C-4202O061 ) (2)
 See  also  PB-248  150,


 Abstract!   The purpose  of  this  study is  to present  an analysis
 of   the role  of  the  federal  government  in water  development  in
 the  Boise Project  of  Idaho and  Oregon.   As  a  result   of   the
 study  and two   related   support   studies,    conclusions   and
 recommendations  are presented and  discussed.

 Descriptors:  *Water  resources,  *Land development, *Boise River
 Basin,    National  government,   Federal  budgets,   Expenses,
 Demand(Economics), Management,  Decision  making,  Recommendatio-
 ns,  Project planning, Water  consumption,  Objectives

 Idents,fiersi.  Boise project,  Boise(Idaho),  Water utilization.
 Government supports,  NTISDIOWRT

 PB-248 149/7ST    NTIS Prices: PC A03/MF  A01
                               1-35

-------
Problem Identification and RanKing -
Basin Planning Process
                           An Assessment of a Riven
Minnesota  Univ..
Center.**I11inois
         Minneapolis.   Water  Resources
       Univ.   at Urbana-Champaign.   Dept
      Research
      of Urban
Researcn   and
and  Regional    PI anning. *0f f ice   of   Water
Technology, Washington, D.C.
AUTHOR: Blair, 1. P.; Harris, A.; Felstehauser
T.;  Austin, T. A.
E1974C4    Fid: 133, 5A, 91H, 70S   GRAI7819
Jan 78   129p
Rept No: REGIONAL RESEARCH SER-2
Contract:  01-14-31-0001-5140
Project: OWRT-B-057-IA
Monitor: 0«RT-B-057-IA(2)
Prepared   in    cooperation   with    Illinois    Univ.
Urbana-Champaign. Dept. of Urban and Regional Planning.
                                          Lamm,  W.
                                                 at
Abstract:
process of
reviewed,
of efficiency
disciplines:
 The comprehensive,  coordinated and joint planning
the Upper Mississippi  River  Basin  Commission  is
and the process is analyzed according to parameters
    and  equity  representative  of  four  research
    economics,  political science,  engineering and
planning.  Revisions to  the
recommended, as derived from
                   existing  planning  process  are
                  the multi-disciplinary analysis.
Descriptors:   *River  basin  development,  *Mississippi River
Basin, *Regiona1 planning. Assessments,  Ranking,  Evaluation,
Benefit   cost   analysis,   Income,   Optimization,   Citizen
participation,  Decision making,   Systems  analysis,   Linear
programming, Scheduling, Budgeting, Improvement

Identifiers: Tradeoffs, NTISDIOWRT

PB-282 100/7ST   NT IS Prices: PC A07/MF A01
                              1-36

-------
   I

   I

   I

   I

   I
I                    Proceedings of the Conference on Interdisciplinary Analysis of
                    Mater  Resource Systems Held at Colorado University,  Boulder,
                    Colorado, on June 19-22,  1973
  1

  I

  I

  I

  I

 I

 1

 I

 I

 1

 I

 I
Colorado, on June 19-22, 1973

American Society of Civil Engineers, New York.*0ffice of Water
Research and Technology, Washington, D.C.
AUTHOR: Flack, J. Ernest
C5944H3    Fid: 13B, 08H, 05C, 488, 680   GRAI7606
1975   41 Op
Contract: DI-14-31-0001-3757
Project: OKRT-X-126(3757)
Monitor: OWRT-x-126(3757)(1)

Abstract'-   The  Water  Resources  Systems  Committee  of  the
American  Society  of  Civil  Engineers'  Technical Council on
Water Resources Planning and Management saw  a  critical  need
for   developing   an   interdisciplinary  approach  to  water
resources development.  This Conference  was  intended  as  an
effective  means  of  advancing  the  systems approach in this
area.  Formal papers on  six  interdisciplinary  efforts  were
selected as case studies, around which discussions were built.
These  six  papers  include interdisciplinary studies on:  (1)
largo reservoirs in Africa;  (2)  limnological modeling of the
Great  Lakes:   (3)   geothermal  development;  (4)  the North
Atlantic  Regional  Water  Resources  Study;   (5)   Corps  of
Engineers  planning experience  in the St.  Louis-Maiine Creek;
and (6)  University research in the Wisconsin  River  and  the
Lower  Fraser  River (Brit.  Columbia)  water quality studies.
Discussions are given after each paper.  Included also  is  an
introductory article on the interdisciplinary aspects of water
resources planning and management.

DeacriptorsU.  *Water  resources,   *Water quality management,
*Meetings,  Systems engineering,  Multiple purpose reservoirs,
Africa, Limnology, Mathematical  models, Great Lakes, Geothermy
,   Economic  development,   Ma line Creek,  Civil engineering,
Social   welfare,    Project   planning,    Law(Jurisprudence),
Interactions,   Decision  making,   Missouri,   United States,
California, Wisconsin River, Fraser River

Identifiers:  North  Atlantic  Region(United  States),   Saint
Louis(Missouri), British Columbia, NTISDIOWRT

PB-248 596/9ST   NTIS Prices: PC A18/MF A01
I
                                                    1-37

-------
Report  of  Testing  Special   Task Force Evaluation Procedures
Water Resource Council   for  Poteau  River  Watershed,   Scott
County, Arkansas and Le Flore County, Oklahoma

Son  Conservation Service,  Washington,  D.C.*Water Resources
Council, Washington, D.C.   (308 099)
C7211J1    Fid: 138, 5C   d7621
Dec 69   41 p

Sponsored  in part by Water Resources Council, Washington, D.C.

Abstract:  The report describes the  objectives  of   the  Soil
Conservation   Service  Test  Team   in  applying  methods  ana
procedures for evaluating water and  related   land  development
and   to  give  the physical and economic aspects of the  Poteau
Watershed.

Descriptors:   *Water resources,   *land  development,   *Poteau
Watershed,  Economic factors,  Project  planning.  Benefit cost
analysis,     Income,      Regional    planning.     Objectives,
Recommendations,  Standards, Arkansas, Oklahoma

Identifiers:  Scott  County(Arkansas), Le Flore County(Oklahoma)
 ,  NTISUSWRC

PB-255 910/2ST   NTIS  Prices:  PC  A03/MF A01
                               1-38

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
Rocky  Mountain  Environmental  Research.  Quest  for a Future.
Problems and Research Priorities in the RocXy Mountain Region

Eisenhower  Consortium  for  Western  Environmental   Forestry
Research,   Fort  Collins,  Colo."Forest Service,  Washington,
D.C.*£nv/jledge in each field,   the gaps in knowledge,  and
thus the major needs to be researched.  Each  leader prepared a
documented report of the findings.   A draft of each task force
report  was  sent  for  review  and  the  review comments were
incorporated where pertinent into the final reports  presented
here.

D&scriptors:  *Environmental impacts, Assessments,  Forecasting,
Management   analysis,   Mineral  deposits,  Mines(Excavations),
Human ecology,  Technology,  Utilization,   Land  development,
Recreation,  Rural  areas,   Economic impact,  Structual  timber,
Forage grasses, Mathematical  models,  Water resources,   Sewage
treatment,  Watersheds,  Irrigation,  River basins, Flood control
,  Desalting,  Cloud seeding, Population growth

Identifiers:    Ecosystems,    Energy  resources,   Environmental
impact assessments,   *Rocky  Mountain  Region(Un)ted  States),
NTISEPAO, NTISNSFRA,  NTISAGFS

PB-256 446/6ST   NTIS Prices:  PC A13/MF  A01
                             1-39

-------
Water  Supply and Wastewater in Coastal Areas:  Proceedings of
Southeastern Conference Held on April 2-4, 1975

North    Carolina    Water    Resources    Research     Inst.,
Raleigh.*National   Oceanic  and  Atmospheric  Administration,
Rockville, Md.  Office of Sea Grant.*Coastal  Plains Center for
Marine Development Services, Washington, D.C.
AUTHOR: Stewart, James M.
C5874A4    Fid: 138, 43B*, 680*. 91H, 86M   GRAI7605
1975   194p*
Monitor: NOAA-75120106
Also pub.  as North Carolina Univ.  Sea Grant reprint no.  83.
Sponsored  in  part  by  Coastal  Plains  Center  for   Marine
Development Services, Washington, D.C.

Abstract:    The   article  details  the  proceedings  of  the
southeastern conference on  Water  Supply  and  Wastewater  in
Coastal  Areas.   The  Conference  was conducted to review the
state of the art of proper planning and  management  of  water
supply  and  wastewater  disposal  in  coastal areas.  Special
attention was paid to defining technological  and institutional
alternatives,   their  relation  to  land  use  planning   and
environmental  protection,  and to identifying those water and
wastewater problems of significance in coastal areas.  A major
problem  that  was  discussed  at the conference is associated
with increasing population growth and economic development  in
these  areas  is  the  provision  of   safe  and adequate water
supplies and management of wastewater discharges in  a  manner
consistent  *ith  public  health and  welfare and environmental
protection. Both the presentations and discussion sessions are
included in the report.

Descriptors:   *Water  supply,   *Water  pollution,   *Coasts,
*Meetings,  *Regional planning,  Waste water,  Reviews,  Water
quality management,  Sewage disposal,  Technology  assessment,
Land  use  zoning,  Environmental impacts,  Population growth,
Economic development,  Public health,  Social welfare,   Water
resources,   Sanitary  engineering,   Project planning,  Ocean
environments, Financing
Identifiers:
NTISCOMNOA
Sea Grant program,   *Environmental  protection,
PB-248 297/4ST   NTIS Prices: PC A09/MF A01
                           1-40

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I








 I
The  Winooski  Workshops:  An Assessment of Specified Workshop
Techniques for Stimulating and Improving Public Involvement in
Water Resources

Vermont  Univ.,    Burlington.    Water   Resources   Research
Center.*0ffice  of Water Research and Technology,  Washington,
D • C •

Completion rept.
AUTHOR: Wi Im, Ann S. ;  Thomas, Kristi L.
C7602H1    Fid: 138, 5K,  488, 68D, 92C, 92B, 43F   GRAI7624
1975   99p
Contract: DI-14-31-1-5046
Project: OWRT-A-020-VT
Monitor: OWRT-A-020-VT(1)

Abstract:  Public participation   is  a  dynamic  communication
process  within  a social system,  a source of information and
support for social and economic goals.   Current  interest  in
Citizen  participation  is sparked by changes in social  values
and more specifically by a change in the  public's  perception
of government responsibility.  Vermont is drawing up its River
Basin Water Quality plans for the major rivers of  the  state.
Agencies  have  called  for  citizen  input.  This provided an
opportunity to test a commonly  used  workshop  technique  for
invo'ving  citizens  against  a second format which involved a
more  socia 1-psycho 1ogical   orientation'   and   small   group
problem-serving techniques. The purpose of this project  was to
test the hypothesis that  differences in environmental  settings
reflect,   and  are  reflected in citizen motivation levels to
become involved in water  resource decision-making.

Descriptors:  "Citizen participation, *Water resources, *Social
communication,  *River  basin  development,   *Water  quality,
*WinoosM  River,    Decision  making,   Economic  development,
Attitude   surveys,    Social   psychology,    Questionnaires,
Environments, Vermont

Identifiers-:  NTISOIOWRT

PB-257 545/4ST   NTIS Prices: PC A05/MF A01
                                1-41

-------
 1.5  Alphabetical Listing of Methodology Abstracts

 1.  An Analysis of Federal Water Resource Planning and Evaluation
     Procedures.

 2.  An Analysis of Water Resource Benefit Determination Methods with
     Special Reference to the Consumnes River Division Project.

 3.  Analytical Techniques for Planning Complex Water Resource Systems.

 4.  A Bargaining Approach for Programming Least-Cost Waste Treatment
     Along a River.

 5.  Comprehensive Framework Study Missouri River Basin.  Volume 7.
     Appendix.  Plan of Development and Management of Water and Related
     Land Resources.

 6.  Development of Regional Supply Functions and a Least-Cost Model
     for Allocating Water Resources in Utah:  A Parametric Linear
     Programming Approach.

 7.  Economic Optimization and Simulation Techniques for Management
     of Regional Water Resource Systems.

 8.  Estimation of Outdoor Recreational Values,

 9.  Evaluating Tisza River Basin Development Plans Using Multiattributes
     Utility Theory.

10.  Federal Evaluation of Resource Investments:  A Case Study.

11.  The Impact of Energy Resource Development on Water Resource
     Allocations.

12.  Improving Institutional Arrangements for Water Development in the
     State of Washington:  Developmental and Environmental Trade-Offs
     and Constrai-nts.

13.  Issues Related to Interfacing Water Resource Planning and Land Use
     Planning:  Development and Application of Quantitative Procedures.

14.  Methodology to Evaluate Alternative Coastal Zone Management Policies:
     Application in the Texas Coastal  Zone.  Example Application III,
     Environmental and Economic Impacts of Recreational Community Develop-
     ment, Mustang Island and North Padre Island,  Volume II - Appendix.

15.  Mixed Integer Programming Models  for Water Resources Management.

16.  Multiple Objective Redesign of the Big Walnut Project,
                                   1-0.9

-------
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
17.  Multiple Objectives Planning Water Resources.  Volume 1.  Natural
     Resources Series Number 5.

18.  Ohio River Basin Comprehensive Survey.  Volume XII.  Appendix K.
     Development Program Formulation.

19.  Optimal Solution to the Timing, Sequencing, and Sizing of Multiple
     Reservoir Surface Water Supply Facilities When Demand Depends on Price.

20.  Optimization Model of Energy Related Economic Development in the Upper
     Colorado River Basin under Conditions of Water and Energy Resource
     Scarcity.

21.  Plan for Development of the Land and Water Resources of the Southeast
     River Basins.  Appendix 10.  Hydrology.  Appendix 11.  Engineering
     and Cost.

22.  Planning of Regional Water Resource Systems for Urban Needs.

23.  Proceedings:  The Connecticut River System:  A Workshop on Research
     Needs and Priorities Held at the University of Massachusetts, Amherst
     on April 24 and 25, 1975.

24.  Project Evaluation in Water Resources:  Budget Constraints.

25.  River Basin Simulation as a Means of Determining Operating Policy
     for a Water Control System.

26.  Significant .Interrelationships Between Electric Power Generation and
     Natural and Developed Resources in the Connecticut River Basin.

27.  Systems Simulation of Economic Factors and Their Relation to the
     Water System of Wyoming's Platte River Basin.
                                  1-43

-------
1.6  Methodology Abstracts
                                  1-44

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
                        Procedures"*  ^  re°Sra>  W3teP  Res°^e  Planning and Evaluation
|                      340)i9an UniV''  An" ArbOP- SCh°°' of Na^ral
I
I                        water   resources   plan  and  0'™-=,.*"— *",'•"'• a sel or  new
                        published ay thTspec a? TaS FOP J  «   ®valuatfon  Procedures
                        used a designated stretch of  t£T  fophJune ^SS. The seminar
                        and   Sayres,     Pennsy?van a   as  ?hfa^ ?etWee"  Pittst°n
                        Investigation.          vanta   as  the   focal   point  of  the
                        dun 70   1i4p
                        Monitor: 18
                       Identifiers: NTISUSWRC
                       l>8-255 498/8ST   uris Prices: PC A06/MF ADI
I

I

I

I

I

I

I
I                                                 1-45

-------
An  Analysis  of  Water Resource Benefit Determination Methods
with Special Reference to the Cosumnes River Division Project

California Univ., Davis. Dept. of Agricultural  Economics.    (
405 609)

Interim rept.
AUTHOR: Tratz. Robert F. Or; Dean, Gerald W. ;   Carter,  Harold
0.
C2163C3    Fid: 13B, 5C, 488   GRAI7404
Jun 73   149p
Contract: 01-14-06-200-5075-A
Monitor: 18

Abstract: The general objective of this study  is to formulate,
construct,  and test a  theoretical  model   which  will  allow
measurement  of  the  magnitude  of  net income and employment
impacts of a multipurpose regional water resource development.
This  model  should  improve  upon  the  current   method   of
determining  municipal  and  industrial  (MSI)    water  supply
benefits (i.e.,   most  likely  single  purpose  alternative).
Related  oojsctives  are  to explore the feasibility of basing
municipal and industrial water supply benefits  on the value or
demand for water rather than,  its cost,  and  to  examine  the
tradeoffs among competing uses of water.

Descriptors: *Benefit cost analysis, *River basin development,
"Water resources, Cosumnes River, Multiple purpose reservoirs,
California,    Economic   development,    Regional   planning,
Methodology-; Economic models, Employment

Identifiers: BR

PB-226 029/7   NTIS Prices: PC E06/MF A01

-------
          1   T8Chniques   for-   Planning   Complex   Water  Resourc.

Texas Water  Develooment  Board,   Austin.    System3   Engineering-

Summary rept.
C2951H2    Fid:  138, 488   GRAI7414
Apr 74   66p
Rspt No: 183
Contract: DI-14-31-Q001-3360
Project: OwRR-A-2070(3360)
Moni tor: CWRR-c-2070(3360) ( 3)
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I                                       _,_.._._,      Aiii^aliUll,      We
                       temand(Economics),  Water  rights,  Cost analysis
                       Identi f ie-rs:  Water  utilization,  water requirements,  NTISOWRR
8                     PB-232  158/6    NTIS Prices:  PC A04/MF A01
I
I
I
I
I
         tIhe neP°nt summa^zes the research experience of the

          -'
                      JR
                            1-47

-------
                                                                                    I
                                                                                    I
                                                                                    I
                                                                                    I
A   Bargaining   Approach  for  Programming  Least-Cost  Waste
Treatment Along a River
North Carolina Water Resources Research Inst., Raleigh.*0ffIce
of Water Research and Technology, Washington, D.C.
AUTHOR: Airan, Lalita D.;  Seagraves, J. A.; Airan, Damodar S.
C5801B3    Fid: 138, 05C,  680*, 96A*,  43F   GRAI7604
Jul 75   71p*
Rept No: UNC-WRRI-75-109
Contract: 01-14-31-0001-3952
Project: OWRT-8-054-NC
Monitor: OWRT-B-054-NC(4)

Abstract:  A mode)  is developed for minimizing waste treatment
costs  to  achieve a given stream standard.  An optimum set of
treatment levels  is  calculated  using  available  information
about  the cost of waste treatment and the effects of waste in
different reaches with an  assumed  procedure  for  bargaining
among  waste  dischargers.   Each  discharger is assumed to be
responsible for the quality of water in his reach. The optimum
solution suggests an optimum  set  of  discharge  permits  and
charges.   However,   it does not favor any one administrative
system or distribution of costs.  The model  is  run  to  find
optimum  or  least-cost  waste  treatment  levels for the Neuse
River of North Carolina.  The optimum solution has  much  less
treatment  than is currently being used.  The costs of present
waste treatment are estimated to  be  $3.7  million  per  year
while  the cost of  the optimum set of treatment levels is only
$1.09 mi 11 ion.

Descriptors:  *Sewage treatment,  *Water  quality  management,
*River  basin  development,  *Regional planning,  Mathematical
models, Optimization, Licenses, Cost comparison, Water quality
,  Estimates, Neuse River,  North Carolina, Cost analysis

Identifiers: NTISDIOWRT

PB-247 108/4ST   NT IS Prices: PC A04/MF A01
                             1-48

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
Comprehensive Framework Study Missouri River Basin.  Volume 7.
Appendix.  Plan of Development and  Management  of  Water  and
Related Land Resources

Missouri Basin Inter-Agency Committee   (410365)
D3571K4    Fid: 13B, 8H, 488, 48G   GRAI7724
Jun 69   290p
Monitor: 18
Original contains color plates: All DDC and NTIS reproductions
will be in black and white. See a'so Volume 2, AD-A043 933.
Availability:   Paper copy available from Supt.   of Documents,
GPO, Washington, D. C. 20402. HC $5.25.

Abstract:  The overall objective  was  the  formulation  of  a
framework  plan  which would provide a broad guide to the best
uses,  or combination of uses,   of  water  and  related  land
resources  to  meet  foreseeable  short"  and long-term needs.
Underlying this overall objective,  consideration was given to
(>1)   the timely development and management of these resources
a's essential  aids to the economic development  and  growth  of
the basin; (2) the preservation of resources,  as appropriate,
to insure that they will be available for tneir   best  use  as
needed;   and  (3)   the  well-being  of all the people as the
overriding determinant.

Descriptors:  *6asins(Geographic),  *Water resources, *Planning,
*Cost analysis, Natural resources, Land use, Economic analysis
,  Forecasting, Agriculture, Irrigation systems,  Water supplies
,  Municipalities,  Industries,  Water quality,  Flood control,
Dams, Reservoirs, Elsctric power production, Recreation

Identifiers:  *Missouri River Basin, *Regional planning,  Water
quality management, NTISDODXA

AO-A043 941/4ST   NTIS Prices: MF A01
                            1-4Q

-------
Development  of  Regional  Supply  Functions  and a Least-Cost
Model— for Allocating Water Resources in  Utah:   A  Parametric
Linear Programming Approach

Utah  Water  Research  Lab Logan*Institute for Water Resources
(Army), Fort Belvoir, Va.   (405725)

Final rept.
AUTHOR: King,  Alton B.; Andersen,  Jay C.;  Clyde,  Calvin G.;
Hoggan, Daniel H.
C3882A2    Fid: 138, 483   GRAI7502
Uun 72   169p
Rept No: PRWG100-2
Contract: DACW31-71-C-0063
Monitor: IWR-74-4-Supp-2

Abstract:    The   report   develops   supply   functions  for
agricultural use in ten hydrologic  study  units  in  Utah  by
parametric  linear  programming.  The shadow-price of imported
water to each study unit was determined to show  the  possible
economic  consequence  of  interbasin  transfer.   In general,
imported water is of little or no  value  if  water  presently
being  evaporated  from  Great  Salt  Lake  is  available  for
diversion upstream.  A statewide linear programming allocation
model was developed to meet projected requirements, subject to
various  hydrologic constraints and limits on diversions.  The
primary factor affecting interbasin transfer of Colorado River
water is the degree to which  evaporation  occurs  from  Great
Salt Lake. (Author)

Descriptors: *Water supplies,  *Systems analysis,  Allocations,
Regions,  Optimization,  Mines(Excavations),   Salvage,  Linear
programming,   Restraint,   Mathematical   models,   Hydrology,
Evaporation, Rivers, Economics, Lakes,  Utah

Identifiers: ""Imported water,  Great Salt lake, Colorado River,
Intergovernmental relationships, *Water demand, NTISOODA

AO/A-000 822/7SL   NTIS Prices: PC A08/MF A01
                         1-50

-------

Economic Optimization and Simulation Techniques for Management
of Regional Water Resource Systems

Texas Water Development Board, Austin.

Completion ropt.
C2945H2    Fid: 136, 488   GRAI7414
Feb 74   60p
Rept No: Rept. no. 179
Contract: DI-14-31-0001-3360
Project: OWRR-C-1070(3360)
Monitor: OWRR-C-2070(3360)(2)

Abstract:   The  research  represents  the  final   phase  of a
three-phase research project leading towards  the  development
of  a  computer-oriented  planning  system for use in planning
large,  multibasin systems of reservoirs and connecting  river
reaches and pump-canals. Specifically,  the research defines a
methodology for  finding   an  optimal  size,   operation,   and
staging  of construction of a .'vater resource system with highly
variable   inflows  and  demands  that  are increasing over the
planning horizon and assessing the impacts of such  a  system.
The  computer  programs   developed  during  this  research are
designed to  analyze  a   problem  on  a  monthly  basis  using
historic  or   stochastic  hydrologic  input data sequences,  a
specified demand build-up period,  and  an  economic  life  as
defined  by the user.

Descriptors:   *water  resources,   *River  basin development,
*Project planning, Texas,  Water supply,  Models,  Irrigation,
Economics, Water quality, Systems analysis, Regional planning,
Agriculture, Computer programming

Identifiers: NTISOWRR

PB-232 066/1   NTIS Prices: PC A04/MF A01
                             1-51

-------
Estimation of Outdoor Recreational Values

Florida  Univ.,   Gainesville.   Dept.    of  Food and Resource
Economics.
AUTHOR: Gibbs, Kenneth C.; McGuire, John F. Ill
C3083I2    Fid: 5H, 92C   GRAI7416
Jul 73   62p
Rept No: Economics-53
Contract: 01-14-31-0001-3267
Project: OWRR-8-007-FIA
Monitor: OWRR-B-OQ7-FLM11)

Abstract: A project was initiated at the University of Florida
to estimate the value of water  in  alternative  uses  and  to
determine  the  optimum allocation among the alternative uses.
Basically,  the study was  designed to  develop  and  test  two
types  of  water  allocation  models:   linear programming and
simulation. In order to allocate water  efficiently,  values of
alternative uses must be estimated.  It is the purpose of this
report to: (1) present the procedures used to derive estimates
of economic value, and (2) derive the economic value of 'water
oriented' outdoor recreation in the Kissimrnae River Basin.

Descriptors:   *Water  resources,   *Recreation,    Recreation
facilities, Travel, River  basin development. Regional planning
,  Cost analysis,  Mathematical models, Florida, Kissimmee River
Basin

Identifiers: NTISOWRR

PB-232 503/3   NTIS Prices: PC E03/MF A01
                             1-52

-------

  Evaluating   Tisza   River    Basin   Development   Plans  Using
  Multiattpibutes Utility  Theory


 International Inst.  for Applied Systems Analysis,   Laxenburg
 (Austria).

 Research rept.
 AUTHOR:   Keeney,  Ralph L.;   Wood,  Eric F.;  David,  Laszlo;
 Csontos, Kornel
 E0612L4    Fid:  13B,  8H,  483, 48G   GRAI7807
 Mar 76   30p
 Rept No: CP-76-3
 Monitor: 18

 Abstract: Selecting a plan  to develop the water resources of  a
 region involves  the consideration- of  economic,   environmental,
 social,   and  technical  objectives.    Twelve   attributes are
 defined to  indicate the  degree to which  these  objectives  are
 achieved in  the Tisza  River basin of Hungary.  A preliminary
 multi-attribute   utility  function   is   assessed  over    these
 attributes.    This  is   combined  with   existing   information
 describing   ttie   possible consequences   of   five   alternative
 development    plans  to   yield an  overall   rating  of   their
 desirability.  The  utility function explicitly   indicates   the
 preference   tradeoffs  among  attributes.  Discussion  indicates
 further  uses  of  the utility   function   in   the  planning   and
 evaluation processes.

 Descriptors:   *Water  resources,   *Tisza River,   *River basin
 development,  *Hungary,  Evaluation,  Assessments,   Objectives,
 Economic  factors,   Environmental  impacts.   Social  effect,
 Project planning,   Theorems,    Drainage,  Mathematical  models,
 Water qua.lity, Water storage,   Floods,  Recreation,   Land use,
 Values

 Identifiers: "Tradeoffs,  Energy requirements, NTISIIASA

PB-276 066/SST   NTIS  Prices:  PC A03/MF A01
                              1-53

-------
Federal Evaluation of Resource Investments: A Case Study
Cornell  Univ.,   Ithaca,   N.Y.   Water  Resources and Marine
Sciences Center. *Cornel 1   Univ.,   Ithaca,   N.Y.   Dept.   of
Agricultural  Economtcs.*New York State Coll.  of Agriculture,
Ithaca.
Technical rept
AUTHOR: Kalter
Schultz, David
C7205J2
Feb 70
Rept No:
Moni tor:
Also pub.
Economics,
    Robert J.;  libby,  Larry
   A.; Shabman, Leonard A.
    138,  5C   GRAI7621
                               W.;  Hinman, Robert C.
  Fid!
100p
TR-24
18
 as Cornell  Univ.,  Ithaca, N.Y.  Dept.  of Agricultural
       E.  Res-313.   Prepared in cooperation with New
A.
York State Coll. of Agriculture, Ithaca.

Abstract:  The purpose of the report Is to further improve and
perfect the standards,  criteria and procedures to be used for
water resource development and management for the proposal for
the  Stonewall  Jackson  Reservoir  on West Fork River in West
Virginia.

Descriptors:  *Water resources,  *Land development,   *Project
planning, Investments,  Water quality,  Environmental impacts,
Recreation, Economic impact, Flood control, Regional  planning,
W«st Virginia, West Fork River

Identifiers: *Stonewall Jackson Reservoir, NTISUSWRC

PB-255 788/2ST   NTlS Prices: PC A05/MF A01

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
The  Impact
Allocations
of  Energy Resource Development on Water Resource
Utah Water Research Lab.,  Logan.*0ffice of Water Research and
Technology, Washington, DC.
AUTHOR:  Keith,  John £.;  Turna,  K.  S.J  Padunchai,  Sums!;
Narayanan, Rangesan
FOOG4C4    Fid: 10A, 97   GRAI7901
May 73   109p
Rept No: UWRL-P-78/005
Contract: 01-14-34-0001-6125
Project: OWRT-B-131-UTAH
Monitor: GWRT-B-131-UTAH(1)

Abstract:  A linear programming mode) of the agricultural  and
energy  sectors  of  Utah was used to examine the economically
efficient allocation of water between agriculture and  energy.
Data :'isre collected for agricultural  returns, costs, and water
requirements; energy returns,  costs,  and water requirements;
and water supply costs.

Descriptors:  *Energy source development,   *Water  resources,
*Resource allocation, Utah, Coal, Crude oil, Natural gas, Coal
gasification, Coal liquefaction, Oil  shale, Irrigation, Energy
transport,   Electric power generation,
Economic impact,  Mathematical  models,
Allocations, Planning, Scenarios

Identifiers": NTISDIOWRT
                            Colorado River Basin,
                             Linear  programming,
P8-286 135/9ST   NTlS Prices: PC A06/MF A01

-------
Improving  Institutional  Arrangements for Water Development in
the State  of  Washington:   Developmental  and  Environmental
Trade-Offs and Constraints

Washington    Univ.,    Seattle.     Inst.    of   Governmental
Research.*0ffice of Water Research and Technology, Washington,
D.C.

Project completion rept.  1 Jul  72-30 Jun 75
AUTHOR: Pealy, Robert H.
D2971U2    Fid: 138, 48B, 91H   GRAI7718
Jun 76   193p
Contract: DI-14-31-0001-3848
Project: OWRT-A-057-WASH


Monitor:  OWRT-A-057-WASH(1)

Abstract-"   The networks  of  institutional  arrangements  in   this
study   consist of   federal,   state,    local,    and   regional
organizations,   including the processes  they use   in   planning
and developing  the  functions   of  irrigation,   water supply,
electricity  generation,    navigation,    flood  control,    soil
conservation,     forest    conservation,     fish   and   wildlife
conservation and  outdoor recreation.  The  networks  are   also
expected to  trade off  the values  of  water development  with the
values  of   environmental   protection and growth.  Each of the
networks was originally  designed  to  reach certain objectives:
comprehensive,     multi-purpose,     long-range   planning   and
development  of river basins; economic efficiency;  engineering
or   technical   efficiency;   administrative efficiency;    and
political consensus. The objective of environmental protection
was recently added,  and,  to a  limited degree,  growth  control.
The networks  have achieved only a  moderate degree of success
 in  achieving the  objectives.

Descriptors:    *0rganizations,    *Decision  making,    *Water
resources,    *Washingtcn(State),   State  government,   Project
planning,    Water   supply,    Navigation,     Flood    control,
Conservation,     Objectives,    National    government,   Local
government,    River basin  development,    Economic    factors,
Recreation,    Electric  power  plants,    Management,   Regional
planning

Identifiers:  *Institutional  framework,  *Water  management(Admi-
nistrative) ,  Tradeoffs,  NTISOIOWRT

PB-267 919/9ST   NTIS  Prices:  PC  A09/MF  A01
                               1-56

-------

Issues Related to Interfacing Water Resource Planning and Land
Use  Planning:   Development  and  Application of Quantitative
Procedures

INTASA,  Menlo Park,   Calif.*0ffice  of  Water  Research  and
Technology! Washington, D.C.   (406 193)

Final rept.                                                _ ,
AUTHOR: Davenport, S.;  Jolissaint, C.  H.;  Betchart,  w.  B.,
Rosing, J.; Skurski, K.
00424B1    Fid:  138, 8H, 488*. 91H*   GRAI7703
May 76   227p*
Rept No: IRP-74-01
Contract:  01-14-31-0001-5207
Project: OWRT-C-6057(5207)
Monitor: OWRT-C-6057(5207)(1)
 (PC A11/MF A01)

 Abstract1   The research addresses three of   many  requirements
 for interfacing water and land resources planning:  (1)  Need to
 coordinate  separate  resource  planning activities and assign
 regional, priorities; (2)  need to relate environmental,   social
 and economic benefits and costs of community land use plans to
 similar  decision  criteria  at  the  regional  water resources
 planning  level;   (3)    need  to  quickly   convert  land  use
 information   into  water  resource  requirements  and  costs.
 Results include: (1)  simplified quantitative procedures based
 on  regional  water,   land and mass balance relationships and,
 demonstrated in the Platte River,  Nebraska Level  B  regional
 study;   (2)   an  improved fiscal cost analysis procedure for
 short term land use decisions based on economic,   social   and
 environmental   goals,  demonstrated in Richmond,  Calif.;   (3)
 extension of site development cost models to  analyze  housing
 cost  associated with community use policies,  demonstrated in
 Napa, Cali fornia.

 Descriptors: nvater resources, *Land use,  *Regional planning,
 *River basin development,  Cost analysis,  Water flow,   Social
 effect,  Water pollution control,  Land development,   Benefit
 cost  analysis,   Community development, Mathematical  models,
 Environmental  impacts,   Requirements,   Platte River,  Economic
 impact, Policies,  Nebraska, California

 Identifiers:   Low  flow  augmentation,  R1chmond(California),
 Napa(California),  NTISDIOWRT

 PB-259 331/7ST   NTIS Prices! PC A11/MF A01

-------
Methodology   to   Evaluate  Alternative Coastal Zone Management
Policies:  Application  in the  Texas  Coastal  Zone.   Example
Application    III,   Environmental  and  Economic  Impacts  of
Recreational  Community  Development,  Mustang  Island and  North
Padre  Island.  Volume II - Appendix

Texas   Univ.   at  Austin.   Center  for  Research   in  Water
Resources.*Texas  Office of the Governor,   Austin.    Div.   of
Planning      Coordination.*National     Science    Foundation,
Washington, DC. Applied Science and Research  Applications.    (
406 294)
AUTHOR: Kier,  Robert S.; Fruh, E. Gus
F0585D4    Fid: 138, 483   GRAI7908
1976   674p
Grant: NSF-AEN74-13590-A-01
Monitor: NSF/RA-761639
_See also Volume  1,  PB-290 132._  Sponsored  in part  by  Texas
Office of the  Governor, Austin. Oiv. of Planning Coordination.

Abstract:     This  report   on   an  example  application  of
environmental  and economic impacts of  recreational  community
development    on   Mustang   and  North  Padre  Islands  is  a
continuation of a study to  establish  operational  guidelines
for Texas Coastal  Zone management. Chapters include population
projections    for   scenarios;    assessment   of  recreational
population demands on Mustang and  North  Padre  Islands  with
mode!   examples;     geological    aspects  of  barrier  island
development;   selected biological  data,   water needs and waste
generation of  these islands;  hydronamic and transport modeling
in  barrier   island communities;   economic analysis of oarrier
island development;  structural  engineering calculations,   and
environmental  and  economic  impacts of employing the private
drive concept.  Information is presented  on   land  and  water
resources, on  currents, flooding,  shoreline changes,   and dune
studies. Descriptions of plants,   animals and nutrient cycling
are given for  selected biotopes such as beaches,  salt marshes,
and  grassflats.   Mammals and birds indigenous to the islands
are   described.    Economic   analysis   includes   soft-ware
development outlines of two program designs,  FDISL and SOLVEX.

Descriptors:    *Environmental   impacts,    *Economic  impact,
*Community development,  *Coastal  zone  management,   *Mustang
Island,    *North    Padrs   Island,     Surveys,    Populations,
Oemand(Economics),  Mathematical  models,   Demography,    Dunes,
Beaches,   Water  supply,    Shores,   Vegetation,   Constraints,
Biological productivity,  Wildlife,    Benefit  cost  analysis,
Computer  programming,    Solid  waste  disposal,   Ocean tides,
Hydrodynamics, Sewage treatment,  Flooding,   Nutrients,  Texas,
Recreation

Identifiers:   *Alternative  planning,    Salt marshes,  SOLVEX
computer program,  FDISL computer  program,  NTISNSFRA

PB-290 131/2ST   NTIS Prices:  PC  A99/MF  A01

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
Mixed   Integer   Programming   Models   for  Water  Resources
Management

Utah Water Research lat>.,  Logan.*0ffice of Water Research and
Technology, Washington, D.C.   (405 725)

Project completion rept. 1 Jul 76-31 Dec 77
AUTHOR: Finney, Brad;  Grenney, William J.; Bishop,  A.  Bruce;
Hughes, Trevor C.
E0803I1    Fid: 13B, 630, 48G, 91H   GRAI7809
Dec 77   292p
Rept No: PRWG-198-1
Contract: DI-14-34-0001-7132
Project: OWRT-B-145-UTAH
Monitor: OWRT-B-145-UTAH(1)

Abstract:  A regional  water quality control model is developed
by  finking a steady-state water quality simulation model with
an optimization model.  The ^ater quality simulation model can
be  applied  to  complex  river  systems  .vith  both point and
nonpoint  loads  using   multiple   interdspendent   pollution
parameters  described by either linear or nonlinear equations.
Twelve water quality parameters can be modeled simultaneously:
Four    nonconservat1ve    constituents    (or    conservative
constituents if the decay rate is set equal to zero); coliform
bacteria (MPN);  phosphorus;  biochemical oxygen demand (BOD);
ammonia  (NH3);   nitrate  (N03);    dissolved   oxygen   (DO);
temperature (C); and algae. The water quality model  is used to
generate constraint equations for the optimization model.  The
optimization model is formulated  as  an  integer  programming
problem in which the integer decision variables are wastewater
treatment  levels or diffuse source management practices to oe
determined for each load.  The model ccnsidsrs the addition or
upgrading   of   /nastewater   treatment  with  structural  and
nonstructural  schemes for both  point  and  diffuse  pollution
sources.   A  least  cost  solution  is Found subject to water
quality standards at surveillance points.

Descriptors:    *f?iver   basin  development,    *Water   quality
management,   *Water  supply,   *Sewage  treatment,   *Regional
planning,   Upgrading,   Mathematical   models,   Optimization,
Coliform bacteria, Phosphorus, Ammonia, Algae, Dissolved gases
t- Oxygen,  Biochemical oxygen demand,   Nitrogen,  Temperature,
Computer programs. Subroutines,  Cost  analysis,  Jordan River,
Utah

Identifiers'-  Path of pollutants,  *Model studies, SSAM computer
program, NTISDIOWRT

PB-276 699/6ST   NTIS  Prices: PC A13/MF A01
                           1-59

-------
Multiple Objective Redesign of the Big Walnut Project

Massachusetts  Inst.   of  Tech.,  Cambridge.  Dept.  of Civil
Engineering.*Water Resources Council, Washington, D.C.    (220
010)
AUTHOR: Major, David C.; Bravo, Carlos! Cohon, Oared; Grayman,
Walter; Harley, Brendan
C7204L3    Fid: 138, 5C   GRAI7621
1 Apr 70   64p
Monitor: 18
Prepared   in   cooperation   with  Water  Resources  Council,
Washington, D.C.

Abstract;  The purpose of the report is to discuss the  theory
of multiple objective planning; provide background information
on the Big Walnut project; analyze benefit and cost accounting
by the Corps for their proposed project for the Big Walnut Oam
In Putnam County, Indiana.

Descriptors:   *Water resources,  *Land development,  *Project
planning,  Economic impact,   Benefit  cost  analysis,   Water
quality,   Flood control,  Recreation,  Environmental Impacts,
Regional planning, Standards, Big Walnut River, Indiana

Identifiers: Big Walnut Oam, Putnam County(Indiana), NTISUSWRC
, NT I SMI TEL

P8-255 685/OST   NTIS Prices: PC A04/MF A01

-------
I

I

I

I

•                       Multiple  Objectives  Planning  Water  Resources.    Volume  1
                         Natural  Resources Series Number  5
I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I
Idaho Research Foundation,   Inc.,   Moscow.*0ffice  of  Water
Research and Technology, Washington, D.C.
AUTHOR: Micnalson, Edgar L.;   Englebert,  Ernest A.;  Andrews,
Wade; Stratton, Charles R.
C7491H1    Fid: 138, 5C, 488, 68D, 50B, 70E   GRAI7623
1974   66p
Project: OWRT-X-142(4259)
Monitor: OWRT-X-142(4259)(1 )
Proceedings  of  the  UCOWR  Workshop  on  Multiple  Objective
Planning  and  Decision-Making,   Held at Las Vegas,  Nevada on
July 16-18, 1974.  See also PB-256 740.

Abstract:  The workshop originated as an effort on the part of
the  Committee  for  Education  and  Research  in  the  Social
Sciences of  the  Universities  Council  on  Water  Resources.
During  the  1972  UCOWR  annual  meeting  a  task  force  was
established to identify research topics and  problems  related
to  multiple  objective  planning  and  decision  making.  The
workshop itself was designed to provide a  means  of  exchange
between  federal   agency  planners and university researchers.
Agency planners —  through position papers —  provided basic
input to use in multiple objective planning.

Descriptors: *Water resources,  *Project planning,  'Meetings,
Decision making,    Research  projects,    National   government,
Universities,   Economic development,  River basin development,
Soil conservation,  Fishes,   Construction,   Land  reclamation,
Wildlife, Nevada

Identifiers: *Multiple purpose projects, NTISDIOWRT

PB-256 739/-1ST   NTIS Prices: PC A04/MF A01

-------
Multiple  Objectives  Planning  Water  Resources.   Volume  2.
Natural Resources Series Number 5

Idaho Research Foundation,   Inc.,   Moscow.*0ffice  of  Water
Research and Technology, Washington, O.C.
AUTHOR: Michalson, Edgar l_. ;   Engelbert,  Ernest A.;  Andrews,
Wade; Stratton, Charles R.
C7491H2    Fid: 13B, 5C, 48B, 680, 508, 70E   GRAI7623
1975   127
Project: OWRT-X-142(4259)
Monitor: OWRT-X-142(4259)(2)
Proceedings of the  UCOWR  Conference  on  Multiple  Objective
Planning  and  Decision-Making,  Held at Boise,  Idaho January
14-16, 1975. See also PB-256 739.

Abstract:  The conference discussed was a result of efforts by
the Committee for Education Research in the Social  Sciences of
the  Universities Council on Water Resources.   During the 1972
UCOWR annual meeting, a task group was established to identify
research topics and problems  related  to  multiple  objective
planning  and  decision  making.   At  the  1973  UCOWR annual
meeting,  a resolution  was  passed  calling  for  a  national
Workshop-Conference on the topic.  The Conference was assigned
to allow the university people  to  present  their  ideas  for
public  discussion  by  federal  agency planners:  The present
volume contains tha Conference papers, together with summaries
of the discussion and panels.

Descriptors: *Water resources,  'Project planning,   'Meetings,
Reviews,   Decision making,  Land use,  Policies,  River basin
development,  Pub!ic opinion,  Social  effect,    Universities,
National   government,   Environmental  impacts,   Objectives,
Ecology, Cost analysis, Economic impact, Standards,  Wildlife!
Idaho

Identifiers: 'Multiple purpose projects, NTISDIOWRT

PB-256 740/2ST   NTIS Prices: PC A07/MF A01
                                                                                 \

                                                                                 1

                                                                                 I

-------
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
  I
  I
  I
  ft
  I
 I
 I
 I
 t
 I
I
I
I
Ohio River Basin Comprehensive Survey. Volume XII. Appendix K.
Development Program Formulation

Army Engineer Div Ohio River Cincinnati   (410257)
D3011H2    Fid: 138, 8H, 48B   GRAI7719
Jul 68   317p
Monitor: 18
Original contains color plates: All DOC and NTIS reproductions
will be In black and white. See also Volume 13, AD-A041 280.

Abstracts   This  appendix  presents  background  information,
planning concepts and procedures,  and,  as an end product,  a
generalized  plan  for  the  development and management of the
water and related land resources of the Ohio River Basin.  The
plan,  comprised of a framework of broad-scaled water resource
and related program elements,  outlines the water and  related
land  resource  development requirements within the basin.  It
also accounts for general  land use  and  management  practices
and  water  based  or  enhanced activities that may influence,
benefit by,  or be dependent on  water  resource  development.
Program  elements  of  the  framework  plan were progressively
formulated through integration of  the  various  developmental
opportunities  and  alternatives  judged  to  best fulfill the
needs of the basin.  The plan demonstrates the extent to which
the  water  and  related  land  resources can meet present the
future demands for  water   and  water-oriented  functions  and
services,   the manner in  which these demands can be met,  the
timing and magnituda of developmant required,   and  the  cost
thit  would  be  involved.   Elements outlined herein form the
basis for the Ohio River Basin development program  summarized
and discussed in the Main  Report.

Descriptors:   *0hio  River,   *Basins(Geographic),  *Resource
management,  Land use,  Planning,  '^ater resources,   Economic
analysis, Forecasting

Identifiers: NTISDOOXA

AO-A041 279/1ST   NTIS Prices: PC A14/MF A01
                                                     1-63

-------
Optima)  Solution  to  the Timing,  Sequencing,  and Sizing of
Multiple Reservoir Surface Water Supply Facilities When Demand
Depends on Price                                                                 i

California Univ.,  Los Angeles.*dffice of Water  Research  and                   '
Technology, Washington, DC.   (072 250)
AUTHOR: Moore, Nancy Young
F0343J4    Fid: 138, 48B   GRAI7905                                              j
Jun 77   146p                                                                    1
Contract: DI-14-31-0001-4208
Project: OWRT-C-5184(4208)
Monitor: OWRT-C-5184(4208)(5)                                                     I

Abstract:   A  general  multi-period  planning  model  for the
optimal timing, sizing,  and  sequencing of reservoir additions
to  surface  water  supply is  presented.  The objective of the                   i
model is the maximization of  net economic efficiency  benefits
subject  to  hydrologic  system  constraints.   The  model  is                   I
designed to handle system  increments  which  are  unique  and
interdependent.  Since firm water,  the product of the system,
is dependent on existing reservoir sizes, configurations,  and                   J
hydrologies  a  rational  operating scheme is incorporated into                   1
the optimization. A price-sensitive demand curve which changes
according to a orescribed growth rate is used.  Known reservoir
cost relattcnships which are  a function  of  project  capacity                   j
determine  costs.   A forward  dynamic programming algorithm is                   4
used for solution.  The model  is tested with an application to                   '
the  Eel  River  Project in Nortnern California.  The discount
rate, growth rate, and demand  elasticity are parameterized and
tested over several values.
Descriptors:  *Multiple purpose reservoirs, *Water supply, Size
determination,  Mathematical  .-nods i s,  Dynamic programming,  Cost
analysis,   Demand(Economics),   Sequencing,    Output,  Sewage
treatment,    Water   distribution,     Theses,     Efficiency,
Optimization,    Prices,   Water  consumption,   Rates(Costs),
Computer programs, California

Identifiers:  *Water demand,   Water levels.  Eel rtiver project,
Water resources development, NTISDIOWRT

PB-288 1S5/5ST    NTIS Prices:  PC A07/MF A01
                             1-64

-------
I
fi
I
I
I
I
*
i
i
i

~                   Descriptors:   *Colorado  River  Basin,  *£nergy demand,   *Energy
                     source  development, A codes, C  codes, Coal gasification plants
                     I,    Coal   industry,   Computer  calculations.  Computer codes,
                     Economic development, Economic  impact, Forecasting,   Industry,
                     M  codes, Mathematical models,   Oil sands,  Oil shale  industry,
                     Regional analysis, Thermal power plants, Uranium reserves, USA
£                   ,  Mater resources

I
I
I
I
I
Optimization  Model  of Energy Related Economic Development in
the Upper Colorado River Basin under Conditions of  Water  and
Energy Resource Scarcity

Los   Alamos  Scientific  Lab.,   N.Mex.*Energy  Research  and
Development Administration.   (3820000)
AUTHOR: Morris. G. E.
D3852I2    Fid: 10A, 97G   GRAI7726
Mar 77   570p
Contract: W-7405-ENG-36
Monitor: 18
Thesis.

Abstract:  A mathematical  model  was  designed  for  computer
 analysis  of   the  likely   impact  of  energy development  in  the
 upper  Colorado River Basin  in  the  period  1980   to   1985.    The
 upper   Colorado  River  Basin,   with  its reserves of coal,   oil
 shale,  uranium ore,  petroleum,   and  natural gas  is  regarded as
 an   important  source of  increased  energy  resources.   The  Basin
 now  contains several  major  mature  oil  fields,   seven   major
 hydroelectric   facilities,  and  has  produced the major portion
 of uranium mined  in   the  U.S.   Energy  projects   proposed,
 planned,    or   under construction  in  the  Colorado,  Utah,   and
 Wyoming portions  of  the  Basin   in   1977   include   39 new  or
 expanded  coal  mines,   10 new or expanded  thermoelectric  power
 plants,  eight  oil  shale developments,  one coal  gasification
 plant,   and three  tar  sand projects,  with the possibility of
 increased   uranium   mining  and  milling.   The  model   is  an
 interregional   input-output  depiction  of  economic  activity
 coupled with export,  water,  and  energy  resource  constraints
 and  runs   In   a   linear  optimized   framework.  (ERA citation
 02:043458)
Identifiers:    ERDA/290200,     ERDA/290400,     ERDA/294000,
ERDA/010000, EROA/020000, *£nergy models, NTISEROA

LA-6732-T   NTIS Prices: PC A24/MF A01
I
                              1-65

-------
Plan  for  Development  of the Land and Water Resources of the
Southeast River Basins. Appendix 10.  Hydrology.  Appendix 11.
Engineering and Cost

United  States Study Commission Southeast River Basins Atlanta
Ga   (410288)

Final rept.
D3111J4    Fid! 13B, 8H, 48G, S1H   GRAI7720
1963   145p
Monitor: 18
Original contains color plates: All DOC and NTIS reproductions
will be in blacfc and white.  Appendixes 10 and 11  to  AD-A041
835. See also Appendixes 12 and 13, AD-A041 851.

Abstract: No abstract available.

Descriptors: *Water resources, *Basins(Geograpnic),  "Hydrology
.   *Cost  analysis,   Floods,  Climate,  Ground water,  North
Carolina, South Carolina,  Georgia,  Florida,  Alabama,  Dams,
Reservoi rs

Identifiers: River Basin development, NTISDOOXA

AD-A041 850/9ST   NTIS Prices: PC A07/MF A01
                             1-fifi

-------
I
i
n
I
i
I
a
 i
 i
 i
 t
 i
 i
 t
 i
 i
 *
Planning of Regional Water Resource Systems fop Urban Needs

North Carolina Water Resources Research Inst., Raleigh,+*North
Carolina  Univ.,   Chapel  Hill.   Dept.  of City and Regional
Planning.*0ffice of Water Research and Technology, Washington,
D.C.

Preliminary completion rept.
AUTHOR: Moreau, David H.
E0501G4    Fid: 138, 8H,  48B, 91H, 48G   GRAI7806
30 Mar 72   44p
Project: OWRT-B-021-NC
Monitor: OWRT-B-021-NC(1)
Prepared by North Carolina Univ., Chapel Hill.  Dept.  of City
and Regional Planning.

Abstract:    The  objective  of  this  study  was  to  examine
modifications to existing planning and analytical models  that
are necessary for the development of limited water and related
land  resources  to  serve the needs of several emerging urban
areas within a region that spans several river basins  in  the

Piedmont  of North Carolina.  Three basic tasks were set forth
1n the proposal for the study: (1) Identify emerging needs for
water and related lands within the  region;   (2)   examine  a
limited  set  of  alternative  programs  for  development  and
management of a regional  system;  and (3)  examine adaptations
of   planning   and  regulatory  practices  and  institutional
arrangements to achieve development  of  a  selected  regional
system.   This  report  covers work completed during the first
year of a 2-year project.

Descriptors:   *Water  supply,   *Regional  planning,   *Nortn
Carolina,     Management,    Demand(Economics),    Land   use,
Mathematical models, River basin development, Project planning
,   Yadkin River,  Deep River,  Haw River,   Hydrology,   Water
consumption, Neuse Siver, Stream flow

Identifiers: *Water demand, NTISDIOWRT

PB-275 058/6ST   NTIS Prices: PC A03/MF A01

-------
Proceedings:   The  Connecticut  River  System:  A Workshop on
Research Needs  and  Priorities  Held  at  the  University  of
Massachusetts, Amherst on April 24 and 25, 1975

Massachusetts   Univ.,   Amherst.   Water  Resources  Research
Center.^Massachusetts Univ.,  Amherst.  Inst.   for  Man  and
Environment.*0ffice   of   Water   Research   and  Technology,
Washington, D.C.
AUTHOR:  Erte!, Madge 0.
D3151D4     Fid: 13B, 680, 48B, 91H   GRAI7720
Jut 75   149o
Pept  No: PUD-52; Completion-FY-75-5
Contract: QI-1t-31-0001-5021
Project: OWRT-A-078-MASS
Monitor: OWRT-A-073-M4SS(1)

Abstract:  A workshop on research needs and priorities on  the
Connecticut River system was conducted on April 24-25, 1975 at
the  University  of Massachusetts.  The goals were to generate
mu'ti-disciplinary,  inter-institutional interest in a  future
co-ordinated  research  program,   and define and evaluate the
priorities  of  needed  research.   Working  group  activities
included:   (1)   Modeling  water  Quality  and quantity;  (2)
flood-plain ecosystems; (3)  aquatic ecosystems; (4)   legal and
economic issues; and (5) man/environment relations.

Descriptors: *Water resources, ^Connecticut River,  'Meetings,
Research projects,  Water quality,   Flood  plains,    Ecology,
Recreation,   Law(Jurisprudence),  Mathematical models,  Water
supply,  Regional planning,  Economic development, Massachusetts

Identifiers: Priorities, NTISDIOWRT

PB-268, 837/2ST   NT IS Prices: PC A07/MF A01
                         1-68

-------
I
I
I
I
I
t
i
1
I
I
I
I
fi
I
l
I
i
i
Project Evaluation in Water Resources: Budget Constraints

Massachusetts Inst. of Tech., Cambridge. Ralph M. Parsons Lab.
for   Water   Resources  and  Hydrodynamics.*0ffice  of  Water
Research and Technology, Washington, D.C.   (406 907)

Technical rept.
AUTHOR: Major, David C.; Cohon,  Jared; Frydl, Edward
C5105I1    Fid:  13B, 48B   GRAI7520
Sep 74   303
Rept No: 188; R74-52
Contract: DI-14-31-0001-3720
Project: OWRT-C-3370(3720)
Monitor: OWRT-C-3370(3720)(1)

Abstract:  A multiob lective mathematical programming model was
developed for the Letvgh River,   Pennsylvania,   in locally and
globally  optimal  versions.   Objectives   for   the   Lehigh
representing  each of the four accounts of  the Water Resources
Council's proposed 1370  standards  are  discussed,   and  the
models are formulated for three of these:   increasing national
income,   regional   and  class   income   distribution,    and
environmental  quality.  The design variables in the model are
the reservoirs and power plants considered  in   the  Corps  of
Engineers'    1961  report  on the Delaware  river basin,  which
includes, the Lenign. Runs of the models were made for one, two
and three objectives,   constrained by total and  local  budgets
of  varying size.  Results from the globally optimal  model are
presented.     These   show   the    estimated    effects    on
multidimensional  net  benefit  surfaces  and  on  the  design
variables of the  budget  Constraints,   There   is  a  general
discussion  of  the  nature  and  use of budget constraints in
multiobjective  planning,   and  suggestions  are   mada   for
implementing  the  work  at  the  district  (Corps)  or region
(Bureau of Reclamation) levels.

Descriptors:    *8enefit  cost  analysis,    *Water   resources,
•Project"  planning,    *Water   quality  management,   *Water
management,  *River basin development,   Mathematical  models,
Computerized  simulation,   Linear programming,  Water supply,
Reservoirs,  Lehigh River,   Budgeting,  Cost analysis,   Flood
control,    Stream  flow,   Recreation,   Hydroelectric  power
generation, Economic analysis, Computer programs, Pennsylvania

Identifiers:  *Multipurpose projects, NTISDICWRT

PB-243 567/5ST   NTIS Prices: PC A14/MF A01
                                                   1-fid

-------
River  Basin  Simulation  as  a Means of Determining Operating
Policy for a Water Control System

Florida Univ.,  Gainesville.   Dept.   of  Food  and  Resource
Economics.

Doctoral thesis
AUTHOR: Kiker, Clyde Frederick
C1S13C1    Fid: 138, 488, 521, 601   GRAI7323
1973   123p
Contract: 01-14-31-0001-3287
Project: OWRR-B-007-FLA
Monitor: OWRR-G-007-FLA(7)

Abstract: The problem of dealing with the formulation of water
management  policy  for  the  area of south Florida within the
Central  and  Southern  Florida  Flood  Control  District  was
undertaken.    The   objectives   were   to  (a)   propose  an
organizational framework in which hydrologic,  economic,   and
institutional  aspects  of  the  region  may be used in policy
development, (b) develop a simulation model which includes the
salient hydrologic,  economic,  and institutional features  of
the  Upper  Kissimmee  River  Basin  to serve as a guide,  (c)
demonstrate the usefulness of the simulation model  in  policy
evaluations,   and  (d)   determine the appropriateness of the
approach for use in policy problems encountered  when  dealing
with  a  large region.  A first-generation simulation model of
the hydrologic phenomena and water-oriented activities in  the
Upper  Kissimmee  River  Basin  was  developed.  fiflodels of the
surface water management system, the water use activities, and
the institutional  constraints were  interfaced  with  rainfall
and watershed runoff models.

Descriptors:    (*Florida,   Water  resources),   {*Management
planning,   *Water   resources),    Corrputerized   simulation,
Kissimmee  River  basin,   River  basin development,  Regional
planning,  Organization theory,   Watersheds,   Water  supply,
Surface waters, Decision making, Theses

Identifiers: OWRR

PB-223 961/4   NTIS Prices: PC E05/MF A01

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 i
 i
 i
 i
 i
 i
 i
 t
 t
 i
i
Significant    Interrelationships   Between   Electric   Power
Generation  and  Natural  and  Developed  Resources   in   the
Connecticut River Basin

Federal Power Commission,  Washington,  D.C.  Office of Energy
Systems.
D2224K2    Fid: 10A, 138, 971, 91A, 48B   GRAI7712
Dec 76   280p
Monitor: 18

Abstract:  This report assesses the interrelationships between
hydroelectric  power  and natural resources in an entire river
basin.   It  presents  a  methodology  for   assessing   these
interrelationships   that   has   applicability  in  preparing
comprehensive environmental impact statements on entire  river
basin systems.

Descriptors:    *Hydroelectric  power generation,  *Connecticut
River Basin,  River basin development,  Land use, Social effect,
Economic  impact,   Manpower,    Cost  estimates,    Hydrology,
Hydroelectric power plants, Topography, Environmental impacts,
Natural resources, Energy demand, Electric power demand, Water
resources, Forecasting

Identifiers:  *£nergy source development,  NTISFPC

PB-264 753/5ST   NTIS Prices:  PC A13/MF A01
                                                   1  71

-------
Systems  Simulation  of Economic Factors and Their Relation to
the Water System of Wyoming's Platte Riven Basin

Wyoming Univ., Laramie. Water Resources Research Inst.

Project completion rept.
AUTHOR: Phi 11ips, Clynn
C2392F4    Fid: 138, 488   GRAI7407
Nov 73   52p
Rept No: Ser-40
Project: OWRR-A-005-WYO
Monitor: OWRR-A-005-WYO(1)

Abstract:  That portion of Wyoming  within  the  North  Platte
River  Basin  is  Itkely  to  feel   substantial  pressure  for
development in the next decade.   The availability and cost  of
water  will  be important  considerations in future development
plans for this area.  This study examines  the  potential  for
designing  an  economic  model  of the Basin,   using simulation
techniques of analysis,  for  use  in  evaluating  development
impacts  that  are  likely  to  occur  in  the near future.  A
hydro logic mode! of the Basin is also being developed,   using
simulation techniques,  and it is intended that the two models
will eventually be integrated.  (Modified author abstract).

Descriptors:   *Wyoming,  *River  basin development,   *Economic
mouels, Feasibility, Platte River basin, Water supply, Benefit
cost analysis

Identifiers!  OWRR

PB-227 267/2   NTIS Prices: PC A04/MF A01
                                1-72

-------
I
i
-          1.7  Alphabetical Listing of  Environmental  Ca.se  Studies Abstracts
             1.  The  Cherry Creek-Casselman  River  Environmental  Improvement  Plan.
I

I

I

I
I

I

I

I
f
 2.  Comprehensive Framework Study Missouri River Basin.  Volume 2.
     Appendices.  Historical Perspective of the Missouri River Basin.
     History of the Framework Study.  Existing Water and Land Resources
     Development.

 3.  Development of Water Resources in Appalachia.  Main Report.  Part III.
     Volume B.  Project Analyses, Chapters 8 through 10.

 4.  Evaluation of Estuarlne Site Development Lagoons.

 5.  Genesee River Basin Study.  Study of Water and Related Land
     Resources.  Volume 1.  Summary Report.

 6.  Hawaii Coastal Zone Management Program:  Technical Supplement 2.
     Management of Hawaii's Coastal Zone for Water Quality Objectives.
^           7.   Hydro  Energy  and  Irrigation:   Rakaia  River  Concept  Study.   Summary.
^               Report No. 7.
 8.  Identification of Water Resources Planning Problems in the Metropolitan
     Area of Greater San Antonio and Its Associated Counties.

 9.  Kentucky/Licking River Basins.  Comprehensive Coordinated Joint Plan.
     (CCJP).

10.  Modified and Updated Comprehensive Water and Sewer Plan for Green
     River Area Development District.

11.  Northern Great Plains Resource Program, Water Work Group Report.

12.  Pacific Northwest River Basins Commission Annual Report Fiscal
     Year 1977.
•          13.   People  and  the  Sound.   Outdoor  Recreation  Planning  Report.

            14.   Regional  Ecological Studies.

9          15.   Regional  Response Through  Port  Development:  An  Economic Case Study
                 on  the  McClellan-Kerr Arkansas  River  Project.

a          16.   A River Basin Management Post-Audit and Analysis.
17.   Southeastern New England Study of Water and Related Land Resources.
     Urban Waters Special  Study.
I

f                                              1-73

-------
18.  A Test of Proposed Procedures for Evaluation of Water and Related
     Land Resources Projects.  A Special Study of the Poteau River Watershed
     Project Prepared by the Staffs of the Southwestern Division and Tulsa
     District Corps of Engineers.

19.  A Test of Procedures Proposed by a Task Force of the Water Resource
     Council.  Special Study of the Mountain Home Division, Southwest
     Idaho Water Development Division, and Walla Walla District, Corps
     of Engineers.

20.  A Test of Proposed Procedures for Evaluation of Water and Related
     Land Resources Projects.  A Special Study of Stonewall Jackson Lake,
     West Ford River and Tributaries, West Virginia.

21.  A Test of Proposed Procedures for Evaluation of Water and Related
     Land Resources Projects.  A Special Study of the Detroit River, Trenton
     Channel Project.

22.  Testing of Evaluation Procedures on Possible Development of the Lower
     Hiwassee River.

23.  Water Resources of Northeast North Carolina.

24.  Water Resources Appraisal for Hydroelectric Licensing Kern River
     Basin, California.

25.  Water Resources Appraisal for Hydroelectric Licensing, Clarion River
     Basin, Pennsylvania.

26.  Water Resources Appraisal for Hydroelectric Licensing.  Kings River
     Basin, California.

27..  Water Quality Management Element for the Kentucky River Area Development
     District.  Comprehensive Water and Sewer Plan.

28.  Water Resources of the Upper Neuse River Basin, North Carolina.

29.  Water Resources Appraisal for Hydroelectric Licensing, Winton
     Development, Kawlshiwi River Minnesota.

30.  Water Supply Dilemmas of Geothermal Development in the Imperial Valley
     of California.

31.  The Willamette Basin Comprehensive Study of Water and Related
     Land Resources.  Appendix J.  Power.
                                    1-74

-------
 I
 I
 —          1.8   Environmental Case  Studies Abstracts
 9
 I
 I
 1
 I
 I
 f
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
 •                                            1-75

-------
The  Cherry  CreeK-Casselman  River  Environmental Improvement
Plan

Maryland Dept.  of  Natural   Resources,   Annapolis.    Program
Planning   and  Evaluation.*Appalachian  Regional  Commission,
Washington, D.C.

Final rept.
AUTHOR: Hecht, Louis G. Or
C4981L3    Fid: 138, 05C, 488,  680, 91H   GRAI7518
dan 74   57p
Grant: ARC-72-47/RP-228
Monitor: ARC-72-47-Jan-74

Abstract:  The survey xas conducted  to  davelop  a  plan  for
environmental  improvement  of   the Cherry Creek Sasin and the
Maryland portion of the Casselman River  Basin.   It.   included
identification   and   evaluation   of   environmental   needs
associated «ith  coal  mining,    sewerage,   solid  waste  and
industrial  operations  as  well as resource development needs
associated  with   water   supply,    community   development,
transportation,    and   general   land   use.   Environmental
restoration was the main priority. Each prcolem is asses3ea in
terms of its contribution to the overall  degradation  of  the
watershed  and  the  current status of corrective action.  The
plan  provides  a  frameworu  for  consideration  of    funding
individual  or  group  environmental  improvement in the Cherry
CreeK-Casselman River watersneds.

Descriptors:  *Water pollution,  *Regional planning,    *Cherry
Creek, *Casselman River, Environmental protection, Coal mining
,    Solid  waste  disposal.   Industries,  Water supply,  Water
resources,  Land use,  Transportation,  Economic  development,
Watersheds, Maryland

Identifiers: *Mine acid drainage,  NTISAPPRC

PB-242 767/2ST   NTIS Prices: PC A04/MF A01
                          1-76

-------
I
I
I
I
t
i
i
i
i
i
i
i
i
i
i
i
i
i
i
Comprehensive Framework Study Missouri River Basin.  Volume 2.
Appendices.  Historical  Perspective  of  the  Missouri  River
Basin. History of the FrameworK Study. Existing Water and Land
Resources Development


Missouri Basin Inter-Agency Committee   (410365)
0357103    Fid:  13B, 8H, 438, 48G   GRAI7724
dun 69   178p
Monitor: 18
Original contains color plates: All DDC and NTIS reproductions
will be In black and white. See also Volume 3, AD-A043 937.


Abstract:   Contents:   Historical Perspective of the Missouri
River Basin;  History of the Framework  Study;   and  Existing
Water and Land Resources Development.


Descriptors: *Basins(Geographic),  *Water resources,  'Resource
management,  *Cost analysis,  Land  use,   History,   Economic

analysis. Hydrology, Water supplies, Water distribution, Water
conservation, Irrigation systems,  Recreation, Dams, Reservoirs
, Capacity(Quantity)


Identifiers: *Missouri River Basin,  *Reg1onal planning,  Land
development, NTISDODXA


AD-A043 936/4ST   NTIS Prices: PC A09/MF A01
                               1-77

-------
Development  of  Water  Resources in \ppalachia.  Main Report.
Part III. Volume 8. Project Analyses, Chapters 8 thru 10

Corps of Engineers Cincinnati  Ohio   (410111)
D3014A1    Fid: 13B, 8H,  48B,  48G -  GRAI7719
Nov 69   422p
Monitor! 18
Original contains color plates: All DDC and NTIS reproductions
witl be in black and white. See also Part 3, Volume 9, AD-A041
395.


Abstract:  This volume is one of six that comprise  Part  III,
"Project  Analyses',   to  the  Main Report for Development of
Water Resources in Appalachia.  The volume contains  three  of
the  20 chapters that make up Part III.  Chapters 8 and 9 were
prepared by the U.S. Army Engineer District,  Mobile.  Chapter
8,   Dalton Reservoir Project,  presents a plan for a multiple
purpose reservoir development on the Conasauga  River,   about
six miles southeast of Dalton, Georgia. Chapter 9, Coosa River
Navigation  Project,   presents  a current reevaluation of the
economic  justification  for  the   authorized   Coosa   River
Navigation Project from Montgomery, Alabama, to Rome, Georgia.
Chapter 10,  Stannard Reservoir Project,  prepared by the U.S.
Army Engineer District,   Buffalo,   presents  a  plan  for  a
multiple  purpose  reservoir development on the Genesee River,
about four miles south of Wellsville, New York.

Descriptors:  *Water  resources,   *Reservo1rs,   Dams,   Cost
analysis, Cost benefits,  Hydrology, Planning,  Water supplies,
Flood control,   Recreation,   Navigation,   Locks(Waterwavs),
Georgia, Alabama, New York, Pennsylvania, Rivers

Identifiers:   *Appalachian  Mountain  Region(United  States),
NTISOODXA

AO-A041 394/8ST   NTIS Prices: PC A18/MF A01
                                 1-78

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
1
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
 I
Evaluation of Estuarlne Site Development Lagoons

Rutgers - The State Univ., New BrunswicK, N.J. Water Resources
Research   Inst.*0ffice  of  Water  Research  and  Technology,
Washington, D.C.


Final  rept.
AUTHOR: Walton, Grant  f.; Nieswand, George H.;  Toth,  Stephen
J. ; Stillman, Calvin W.; Westman, James  R.
D1335L2    Fid: 138, 5K, 680, 91H,  92C   GRAI7706
1  Jul  76   187p
Contract: 01-14-31-0001-3614
Project: OWRT-B-040-NJ
Monitor: OWRT-B-040-NJ(5)
Abstract:  A large number of estuarine site development lagoon
systems have been constructed along the New Jersey shore  with
little,   if  any,  Knowledge regarding the true nature of the
system being Created and its impact on  the  existing  natural
estuarine  system.   A  comprehensive  study and evaluation of
these  lagoon systems was undertaken including consideration of
the  physical,    chemical,     biological    and   socioeconomic
conditions.    In  terms  of the socioeconomic conditions,   the
residents are generally  quite  satisfied  with  their  lagoon
hornet  in  spite  of  their  perception of major pollution and
over-development problems.

Descriptors: *£stuaries, *Land development, * Lagoons(landform-
9), *Water pollution, *New Jersey, Bays(Topographic features),
Water  flow,  Marshes, Site surveys, Planning,  Economic impact,
Environmental impacts, Shores, Tidewater,   Evaluation,  Social
effect

Identifiers: *Wetlands, *Salt marshes, NTISDIOWRT

PB-261 367/7ST    NTlS Prices: PC A09/MF A01
                             1-79

-------
Genesee  River  Basin  Study.  Study of Water and Related Land
Resources' Volume 1. Summary Report

Corps of Engineers Buffalo N Y Buffalo District   (410090)

Final rept.
D3J03I4    Fid: 13B, 48B, 680, 91H   GRAI7720
Jun 69   219p
Monitor: 18
See also Additions to Summary Report,  AD-A041 701 and  Volume
2..AD-A041 703.

Abstract:   The Genesee River Basin covers 2,479 square miles,
mostly in western New York,  with a small portion,  96  square
miles  in  northwestern  Pennsylvania.  The river rises in the
Allegheny highlands in Potter County,   Pennsylvania,   at  an
elevation  of about 2,500 feet,  flows aporoximately 157 river
miles in a generally  northward  direction  to  its  mouth  at
Rochester Harbor on LaKe Ontario, at an elevation of about 247
feet. The topography of the southern portion, the Upper Basin,
upstream of Mount Morris Dam,  is steep and rugged,   while the
northern portion, the Lower Basin, is gently rolling.  The two
major  divisions  of  the  basin also closely parallel the two
land resource areas which comprise the basin:   the  Allegheny
Plateau and the Ontario LaKe Plains Service Area,  a region of
about 750 square miles north  and  west  of  the  Basin  lying
between Rochester and Lockport, New York.  The principal needs
are for flood protection,  water quality control,  recreation,
fish  and wildlife enhancement,  irrigation,  and agricultural
land and water management.   The  most  practicable  means  to
provide  for  these  and other needs of the basin is through a
comprehensive plan of structural and non-structural  measures.

Descriptors: *Basins(Geographic), *Water resources,   New York,
Pennsylvania,   Flood  control,   Water  quality,  Recreation,
Wildlife, Irrigation systems, Land use, Topography,   Planning,
Economic analysis, Lakes, Reports, Rivers
Identifiers:   *Genesee
Ontario, NTISDODXA
Ri ver,
Economic  development,   Lake
AD-A041 702/2ST   NTIS Prices: PC A10/MF A01
                          1-80

-------
I
I
I
I
                     Hawaii   Coastal  Zone Management Program:   Technical  Supplement
                     2.   Management  of Hawaii's  Coastal   Zone  for  Water  Quality
                     Objectives

                     Hawaii     Univ.,      Honolulu.     Water   Resources    Research
                     Center.*National   Oceanic  and    Atmospheric   Administration,
                     Rockville, Md.  Office of  Coastal  Zone Management.*Hawaii  State
                     Oept. of Planning and Economic  Development,  Honolulu.
                     AUTHOR:  McGauhey, P. H.;  Lau,  L.  Stephen
                     C7135H3     Fid:  13B, 488, 680,  86R   GRAI7620
                     Aug 75    54p
                     Monitor: NOAA-76032405
                     Prepared  for  Hawaii  State  Dept.    of  Planning  and Economic
                     Development, Honolulu. See also PB-255 336 and PB-255 338.

                     Abstract:    The   paper  presents   an  overview  of  wastewater
                     management  as   related   to  the   quality  of Hawaii's coastal
                     waters.   It  examines  concepts  for  establishing  an  inland
                     boundary of the  coastal  zone,  and reflects some of the results
                     of   studies  made during  the course  of the 'Quality  of Coastal
                     Waters'   project  supported principally by  the  University   of
                     Hawaii  Sea Grant  Program  during the  years 1971 to  1975.

                     Descriptors: *Coastal zone management, *Water quality, *Hawaii
                     ,    Water  pollution,   Waste water,  Sewage treatment,   Ocean
                     environments,  Sewage disposal,  Boundaries,  Runoff,   Ground
                     water,  Land use


                     Identifiers: NTISCOMNOA,  NTISUH

                     P8-255  337/8ST    NTIS Prices:  PC  A04/MF A01
1-81

-------
Hydro  Energy  and  Irrigation:   Rakaia  River Concept Study.
Summary. Report No. 7

New  Zealand  Energy  Research  and   Development   Committee,
Auckland.   (4670300)                        r-D&TT-roq
D1833A1    Fid: 138, 2C, 10B, 508, 971, 98   GRAI7709
Mar 76   21 p
Monitor: 18
Microfiche copies only. U.S. Sales Only.

Abstract:   This report presents  three schemes for storage and
 control of the Rakaia  River so that  better  use can  be made   of
 the water  for irrigation,   power  development,  and  recreation.
 One scheme is recommended  for  further  study.  Stage  development
 of the scheme is  presented  for  partial   or   full   operation.
 Environmental  effects  are  considered  and   at this level  of
 study it appears  that  there are no insurmountable problems.  In
 fact this  development  should  enhance   recreational   uses  and
 fishing.   Preliminary  cost studies indicate that  feasibility
 studies would be  worthwhile to determine cost benefits in more
 detail and environmental  impact.  (ERA  citation 02:010126)

 Descriptors: *Hydroelectric power plants, irrigation,  *Water
 reservoirs, New Zealand,   Agriculture,  Cost  benefit analysis,
 environmental effects. Feasibility studies,  Power generation,
 Rivars, Storage,  Surface waters,  Water resources

 Identifiers:     ERDA/290300,      ERDA/296001,    ERDA/130600,
 Recreational facilities,  Fishing, Cost estimates, Rakaia River
 , NTISERDAE

 NP-21133   NTIS Prices: MF A01
                              1-82

-------
I
I
I
I
I
                         Identification  of   Water   Resources  Planning Problems In the
                         Metropolitan Area of Greater  San  Antonio  and  its   Associated
                         Count i es

                         Texas  A and M Univ., College  Station.   Water  Resources  Inst.

                         Technical  rept.  1 Jul  70-30 Apr 73
                         AUTHOR:  Garner,  Joseph K.;  Shih,  C.  S.
                         C1424K1     Fid:  138, 601    GRAI7318
                         Oun 73    160p
                         Rept No:  TR-49
                         Contract:  01-14-31-0001-3244,  01-14-31-0001-3544
                         Project:  OWRR-A-017-TEX
                         Monitor:  GWRR-A-017-TEX(2)
                         Also sponsored by Contract  01-14-31-0001-3844.

                         Abstract:    The  region  incompasseri  by the  San  Antonio  River
                         Basin  is described.    Included is   a   brief   summary   of   the
                         regional      economy,       demography,      and   geographical
                         characteristics.     Additionally,    quantitative    information
                         including  the inventory and  planning  control  for both  surface
                         and groundwater  resource management  of  the San Antonio  area is
                         presented.    Empnasis  has been placed  uoon the  identification
                         of   tne   probabilistic  nature  of  regional  water   quality
                         irsnagement.   The  methods and  techniques developed for handling
                         massive data and  the reliability  analysis  for   regional  water
                         quality control  are  also presented.

                         Descriptors:   (*Water  resources,   Texas),   (*Water quality,
                         *Texas),  Regional planning, Economic development,   Demography,
                         Sites,    Inventories,   Urban  areas,  Rural  areas,   Management,
                         Reliability, San  Antonio River Basin,  Reviews

                         Identifiers: *San Antonio(Texas), OWRR

                         PB-222  182/3   NTIS  Prices: PC A08/MF  A01
1-83

-------
Kentucky/Licking River Basins. Comprehensive Coordinated Joint
Plan. (CCJP)

Ohio River Basin Commission, Cincinnati.
E2591C2    Fid: 13B, 680, 48B, 91H   GRAI7824
Apr 77   139p
Rept No: 510
Moni tor: 18
                                              summary  of  the
                                               it  now  exists
Aostract:    The  plan  summary  contains  a
Commission's adopted plan for development  as  , ,.  ,,uw  =^131.=.
including conclusions and recommendations. Priorities contains
the   Commission's  recommendations  for  the  collection  and
analysis of basic data and for  investigation,   planning  and
construction  of  projects.    The  direction  for  the  future
contains the State,  Federal  and adopted Commission  policies,
goals  and  planning  objectives  and economic and demographic
projections  used  by  Commission  members.   Baseline  record
contains  a  list  of  all identified alternative projects and
programs,   whatever  their   stage  of  development.    (Colon
illustrations reproduced in  black and white)

Dsscriptors: *Regional planning,  *Water resources,  *Kentucky
River Basin,  flicking River  Basin,   Surveys,   Construction,
Project planning, State government, National government, Local
government, Economic development, Demography, Conflicts, Water
pollution,  Water supply,  Maps,  Ohio River,  Kentucky River,
Licking River,  Indiana, Ohio
PO
Lie!

ICer.tif iers:
NTISSLRS
              Priorities,   Water  management(Admlnistrat1ve),
PB-284 293/8ST   NTIS Prices.1 PC A07/MF A01
                                  1-84

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
Modified  and  Updated  Comprehensive Water1 and Sewer Plan for
Green River Area Development District

Kentucky Office for Local Government, Frankfort.
C1584E3    Fid: 13B   GRAI7320
20 Uun 73   353p
Rept No: CK-OLG-73-34
Project: HUO-CPA-KY-1000
Monitor: 18
Prepared in cooperation with Weston (Roy F.), Inc..  Wi Imette,
111.

Abstract:    The   regional  plan  includes  a  study  of  the
socio-economic factors, land use,  and water resources.   Water
service  areas  and  sewer service areas have been delineated,
new treatment facilities or expansion of  existing  facilities

were  proposed.   Water quality management considerations have
been presented and the short-range and  long-range  priorities
have  been  delineated.  Construction and operating costs have
been estimated presented for the proposed systems.

Descriptors: (*Regional planning, *Kentucky),   (*Water supply,
Regional planning),  (*Sewers,  Regional planning),  Land use,
Water resources,  Water quality,   Construction,   Facilities,
Economic analysis

Identifiers: UPCD

PB-223 -058/9   NTIS Prices: PC E10/MF A01
                          1-85

-------
Northern  Great  Plains  Resource  Program,    Water Work Group
Report

Northern   Great    Plains    Resource    Program,      Denver,
Co1o.*Department of Agriculture,  Washington,   D.C.*Oepartment
of the Interior,  Washington,   D.C.*Environmental   Protection

Agency, Washington, D.C.
C5051H3    Fid: 138, 081,  48B,  48A   GRAI7519
Dec 74   333p
Rept No: NGPRP/CD-74/200
Monitor: 18
Prepared   in  cooperation  with  Department  of  Agriculture,
Washington,  D.C.,   Department  of the  Interior,   Washington,
D.C.,  and Environmental  Protection Agency,   Washington,  D.C.
See also PB-243 149 and PB-243  151.

Abstract'-  The report analyzes  surface water resources of  the
Upper  Missouri River Main Stream and Yellowstone Basin with a
brief analysis of the ground water resources  in  Montana  and
Wyoming.    Constraints  to  water  resource  development  are
analyzed along witn historical   resource  development,   water
availability above present uses,  cost of  delivery in Wyoming,
Montana,  and North Dakota.  A  separate report is included  on
in-stream  needs.  It projects  amounts of  water that should be
left in streams  to  maintain  present  riparian  and  aquatic
habitats-   It  assumes  that  there is a  need for maintaining
fluctuating annual  flows  rather than traditional minimum level
flows.  A separate report Is included on the wild  and  scenic
river  recreational  values  of Upper Missouri and Yellowstone
Basin streams that may be affected by coal  development.

Descriptors: *Water resources,  *Surface waters, *Ground water,
*Missouri River,  *Yellowstone  Basin,  Water supply,  Economic
development,   Cost  analysis,    Stream  flow,   Coal  mining,
Recreation, Water rights,   Environmental impacts,  Water flow,
North Dakota, Montana, Wyoming,  Northern  Plains Region(Un1ted
States)

Identifiers: *W11d rivers, *Scenic rivers,  NTISEPAG, NTISAGOS,
NTISDIOS

PB-243 150/OST   NTIS Prices: PC A15/MF A01
                          1-86

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
1
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
Pacific Northwest Riven 3as;ns Commission Annual Report Fiscal
Year 1977

Pacific   Northwest   River   Basins  Commission,   Vancouver,
Wash.*Water Resources Council, Washington, D.C.
E2S62L1    Fid: 13B, 483,  68D   GRAI7825
Sep 77   24p
Monitor: 18
Sponsored in part by Water Resources Council,  Washington,  D.C.
_See also report dated 1976, PB-280 947._


Abstract:  This report reflects the work accomplished  by   the
Pacific  Northwest  River   Basins  Commission  for fiscal  year
1977,  also brief highlights of the decade of the Commission's
existence.  (Color illustrations reproduced in black and white)

Descriptors:   *Research  projects,   *Water resources,  Water
supply, Organizations, Land use,  Estuaries, Salt water,  Water
quality,   Economic  development,   Idaho,   Montana,  Oregon,
Washlngton(State), Wyoming


Identifiers: NTISUSWRC

PB-284 940/4ST   NTIS Prices: PC  A02/MF A01
                               1-87

-------
People and the Sound. Outdoor Recreation Planning Report

New England River Basins Commission,  aoston,  Mass.*8upeau of
Outdoor Recreation,  Philadelphia,   Pa.   Northeast  Regional
Office.
Final rept.
C5465D4 Fid: 138, 05K
Aug 75 127p
Rept No: LISS-05
Monitor: 18
Report on Long Island
Outdoor Recreation, Phi
Office.
Paper copy also avail
233-SET, PCS61.00.
, 91H, 488 GRAI7525
Sound Study. Prepared by
ladelphia, Pa. Northeast
able in set of 14 reports
Bureau of
Regional
as PB-245
Abstract: The planning report describes the outdoor recreation
element of the Long Island Sound Regional  Study. It is part of
the final report of the Study,  which outlines a strategy  for
securing  the balanced conservation and development of natural
resources of the Sound,and its shoreline in both New York  and
Connecticut. The plan for Long Island Sound is an increment of
the   New   England  River  Basins  Commission  comprehensive,
coordinated  joint  plan  for  the  water   and  related   land
resources  of  its region,  which includes New England and the
New York portions of Long Island Sound.

Descriptors:    *Regiona1   planning,    *Natural   resources,
•Recreation,  *Long Island Sound,  Conservation,  Recreational
facilities,   Water resources,  Land  use.    Shores,   Beaches,
Swimming, Economic development, Marinas, Connecticut,  New York

Identifiers: Open space plan, NTISNER3C, NTISDIBOR

P8-245 238/1ST   NTIS Prices: PC A07/MF A01

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
Regional Ecological Studies

Oak Ridge National Lab., Tenn.*Energy Research and Development
Administration.    (4832000)
AUTHOR: McCarthy, M.  M.; Reichle, D. E. ; Betson, R. P.
D10Q5E4    Fid:  13B,  5K, 91H, 97G   GRAI7704
Jul 76   81p
Contract: W-7405-eng-26
Monitor: 18

Abstract:   In  August  of  1974,   the  newly formed Regional
Environmental Assessment group in the  Environmental  Sciences
Division  was asked to  join the Regional Environmental Systems
Analysis (RESA)  Program in a two-month regional case study of
the  Harriman quadrangle in eastern Tennessee.  The objectives
of this effort were to  initiate an  integrated analysis of  tne
environmental  and  socioeconomic   impacts  of energy resource
development in the Tennessee Valley. This report is the result
of   that   two-month   study,     which'    illustrates    the
conceptualization    of   the   problem   approach   and   the
methodologies   previously   developed   by    the    Regional
Environmental  Assessment  group
residual source terms,  land-use
the case study area.   This study
1974,  . without  completion  of
assessment   and  socioeconomic
02:001571)
                     which ware applied to energy
                    and hydrologic  resources  of
                    was discontinued in September
                    the  ultimate   environmental
                    integration.   (ERA  citation
Descriptors:  *Energy  sources,   ""Tennessee,   *Environmental
effects,   Energy demand,  Environment,  Hydrology,  Land use,
Regional analysis,  Socio-economic factors,  Tennessee  River,
Water resources
I dent i fiers:
development,
  ERDA/530100,
NTISEROA
Economic impact,  *Energy source
ORNL/RUS-24   NTIS Prices: PC A05/MF A01
                              1-89

-------
 Regional   Response Through Port  Development:   An Economic Case
 Study on  the McClel lan-K
-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
1
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
                  1944-1972.    The
                  was  documented.
A River Basin Management Post-Audit and Analysis

Little (Authur D.) Inc., Cambridge, Mass.   (208 850)


Final rept.
AUTHOR: Wilkinson, John M.
C1644K1    Fid: 138,  50, 48B*. 521   GRAI7321
Aug 73   276p*
Contract: DI-14-31-0001-3719
Project:  OWRR-C-3353(3719)
Monitor:  OWRR-C-3353(3719)(1)

Abstract:   The  water  management  history  of the Pick-Sloan
Missouri  River Basin  Program  was  analyzed  with  particular
emphasis   on  federal,   State,   local  and  non-governmental
institutional  arrangements and an evaluation of performance of
these institutions over a  28-year  period,
statutory   bases   for  these  institutions
Performance  criteria  included  effectiveness   in   regional
policy,  olanning,  programming and operational management and
their responsiveness to social change.  The  regional  economy
was comoared in 1940 and 1970, in the light of expectations of
the  origins!  plan and actual realization of intended results,
with emphasis  on the role of  water.   The  analysis  prompted
recommendations  for new institutional re-orientations for the
future that  would  better   serve  the  needs   of  multi-State
regional ism.


Descriptors: (*River basin  development, *Government policies),
(*Missouri   River  basin,  River basin development),  History,
Regional  planning, Economic analysis,  Water resources,  Public
administration,   Management  analysis,   Water law,  National
government, State government

Identlfiers: OWRR

PB-222 941/7   NTIS Prices: PC A13/MF A01
1-91

-------
Southeastern  New  England  Study  of  Water  and Related Land
Resources. Urban Waters Special  Study

New England River Basins Commission,   Boston,  Mass.*Econom1cs
Research Associates, McLean, Va.*Skidmore, Owings and Merrill,
Wash-ington, D.C.*Cortel1 (Jason M.) and Associates,  Wellesley
Hi I Is,"Mass.

Final rept.
C7054I4    Fid: 138, 91A, 910, 488, SOB   GRAI7619
Jan 75    181P
Rept No: NERBC-35
Monitor:  18
Prepared by Skidmore, Owings and Merrill, Washington, D.C.

Abstract:  The report incorporates the findings of  the  Urban
Waters  Study  project  for the Southeastern New England Study
Region  (SENE). The study is aimed at the particular issues and
problems  facing the  cities  and  towns  with  waterfronts  on
rivers  or  coastal waters.  The report analyzes the physical,
economic,  ecological,  and   legal  and   institutional   issues
related to urban waterfronts  in the region.  Specific planning
and  design  guidelines   are   recommended,    as   well   as
institutional and  legal mechanisms for implementing waterfront
controls, and guiding improvements.

Descriptors: *Water resources, *Land use, *Urban areas,  Rivers
, Coasts, Harbors, Coastal  zone management,  Policies, Decision
making, Economic development. Industries, Recreation, Beaches,
Marine  terminals,  Law(Jurisprudence),  Conservation,  Ecology,
Massachusetts, Rhode  Island

Identifiers: *Waterfronts,  New England, NTISNERBC

PB-254  818/8ST   -NTIS Prices: PC A09/MF A01
                             1-92

-------

A  Test  of  Proposed  Procedures  for Evaluation of Water and
Related Land Resources Projects.  A Special  Study of the Poteau
River  Watershed  Project  Prepared  by  the  Staffs  of   the
Southwestern Division and Tulsa District Corps of Engineers

Army Engineer District, Tulsa,  Okla.*Water Resources Council,
Washington, D.C.
C7205A2    Fid: 138   GRAI7621
Mar 70   132p
Moni tor: 18
Prepared  in  cooperation  with   Water   Resources   Council,
Washington, D.C.

Abstract: The report is the product of studies made by a Corps
of Engineers Test Team,  which was instituted to test proposed
Water Resources Council evaluation procedures as  outlined  in
'Procedures  for Evaluation of Water and Related Land Resource
Projects'.  An existing  Department  of  Agriculture  plan  of
improvement  on  the  Poteau  River  Watershed in Arkansas and
Oklahoma was analyzed using these guidelines.

Descriptors:  *Water resources,  *Land development,   *Project
planning,   *Poteau  River  Watershed,  Benefit cost analysis,
Objectives,  Economic impact,  Social  effect,   Environmental
impacts, Regional planning, Arkansas, Oklahoma

Identifiers: NTISUSWRC, NTISDODA

PB-255 689/2ST   NTIS Prices! PC A07/MF A01
                             1-93

-------
A  Test  of  Procedures  Proposed by a Task Force of the Water
Resource Council. Special  Study of the Mountain Home Division,
Southwest Idaho Water Development Division,  and  Walla  Walla
District, Corps of Engineers
                    Portland,   Oreg.
                    Washington,   D.C
 North Pacific Div.*Water
*Army Engineers District,
Corps of Engineers,
Resources Council,
Wai la Wai la, Wash.
C7204L2    Fid: 138, 5C   GRAI7621
Mar 70   112p
Moni tor: 18
Prepared  in  cooperation  *ith Army Engineer District,  Walla
Walla, Wash., ?wd Water Resources Council, Washington, D.C.

Abstract:  The proposed procedures in the report calls for  an
evaluation of water resource projects in terms of all relevant
national  objectives,   both  in  measuring  project  effects,
beneficial and adverse,  and in formulating  a  plan  that  is
responsive  to all objectives for the proposal of the Mountain
Home  Project,   Guffey  Dam,   in  Southwest  Idaho.    Color
illustrations reproduced in black and white.

Descriptors:   *Water resources,  *Land development,  *Project
planning, Economic  impact,  Income, Recreation,  Flood control,
Water quality,  Fishes,  Dams,   Standards,  Regional planning,

Environmental impacts,  Idaho, Snake River

Identifiers: *Guffy Dam,  NTISUSWRC,  NTISDODA

PB-255 6S3/5ST   NTIS Prices: PC A06/MF  A01
                            1-94

-------
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
A  Test  of  Proposed  Procedures  for Evaluation of Water and
"elated Land Resources Projects.  A Soecial Study of Stonewall
Jackson Lake, West Fork River and Tributaries, West Virginia

Ohio  River  Div.  Labs.,  Cincinnati.*Army Engineer District,
Pittsburgh, Pa.*Water Resources Council, Washington, D.C.
C7142J2    Fid:  138   GRAI7620
Mar 70   124p
Moni tor:  18
Prepared  in  cooperation   with   Army   Engineer   District,
Pittsburgh,    Pa.   Sponsored  by  Water  Resources  Council,
Washington, D.C«

Abstract:   The purpose of  the  report  is  to  determine  the
advisability  of  modifying  a previously authorized reservoir
located between Weston and Clarksburg, W. Va,  It includes the
S'-Jidelines  and  measurement of the effects of the project for
Stonewall  Jackson Lake.

Descriptors: *Water resources,  *Land use,  *Stonewal1  Jackson
LaKe,  Project planning,  Standards,  Objectives,   Benefit cost
analysis,  Recreation, Economic development, West Virginia

Identifiers: NTISUSWRC, NTISDODA

PB-255 477/2ST   NTIS Prices:  PC AOS/MF A01
                            1-95

-------
A  Test  of  Proposed
Related Land Resources
Detroit River,  Trenton
                       Procedures  for
                        Projects.   A
                       Channel  Project
                                       Evaluation of Water and
                                       Special  Study  of  the
Army Engineer Div. North Central, Chicago,  I11.*Army Engineer
District, Detroit, Mich.   (407 074)
C7203G4    Fid: 13B   GRAI7621
Mar 70   52p
Monitor: 18
Prepared in cooperation with Army Engineer District,  Detroit,
Mich.

Abstract:   The  objective  of  this  report  is  to  test the
workability, as applied to a commercial  navigation project, of
the evaluation procedures prooosed for  the  Detroit  River  -
                                         was authorized in the
                                         benefits and costs of
                                         current interest rate
                                          evaluated.   Second,
                                         mixes of the national
                                         force  report,   were
trenton Channel, Michigan, project which
1968  River and Harbor Act.   First,  the
the project as authorized, adjusted to a
Of 4-7/8 percent,  were  identified  and
alternative  plans,   to  meet  varying
objectives as set  forth  in  the  task
evaluated.   This  report  identifies  benefits which would be
gained by interests other than navigation,  but which were not
presented in the survey report as project benefits.

Descriptors:   *Water resources,   *Land development,  *Project
planning,  *Michigan,  Evaluation,  Navigation,  Benefit  cost
analysis,   Detroit  River,    Regional  planning,   Commercial
transportation,  Comparison,  Economic analysis,   Objectives,
Feasibility

Identifiers: Alternatives, NTISUSWRC, NTISDODA

PB-255 536/5ST   NT IS Prices: PC  A04/MF A01
                           1-96

-------

 Testing  of   Evaluation  Procedures on Possible Development of
 the  Lower Hiwassee  River

 Tennessee  Valley   Authority,    Knoxvllle.*Water   Resources
 Council, Washington, D.C.
 C7204L1    Fid:  138   GRAI7621
 Mar  70   154p
 Monitor: 18
 Prepared   in    cooperation   with  Water  Resources  Council.
 Washington, D.c.

 Abstract:  The report deals  with  trial   application  of  the
 revised  procedures  by  the  Special Task Force Report of the
 Water  Resources  Council.    Methodology  and   approach   are
 emphasized rather than the specific numerical values given for
 items  such  as  benefits and costs.  Portions of this document
 are not fully legible.

 Descriptors:   *water resources,   *Land use,   *Hiwassee  River,
 Research projects, Evaluation, Water quality,  Cost estimates,
 Regional  planning, Flood control,  Recreation, Income, Wildlife
 , Benefit cost analysis, Tables(Data),  Tennessee

 Identifiers:  NTISUSWRC

PB-255 682/7ST   NTIS Prices:  PC A08/MF A01
                              1-97

-------
Water Resources of Northeast North Carolina

Geological Survey Raleigh Nc Water Resources Div   (410804)

Final rept.
AUTHOR: Wilder, H. B.; Robison, T. M.;  Lindskov, K. L.
E2424G2    Fid: 138, 8H, 48B, 48G, 91H   GRA17823
May 78   125p
Rept No: USGS/WRO/WRI-78/070; USGS/WRI-77-81
Monitor: 18

Abstract:   Associated  with economic development of northeast
North  Carolina  are  several  water-related  problems.    The
solution  to  these  problems  depends  in  part  on  adequate
knowledge of the hydrology of this 8,930 square  mile  coastal
area.  Although it is hydro!ogicaI 1y the least studied area of
North   Carolina,    enough   is   known   to   present   this
reconnaiosance-1 eve 1  picture of  its water resources.  Average
annual precipitation on the area  is aoout 50 inches.  Of  this
amount,   about  34  inches  returns  to  the  atmosphere  via
evapotranspiration, about 15 inches leaves the area as runoff,
and aoout one inch leaves through  ground-water  outflow.   No
large  streams  originate  within the area,   but major streams
entering from the north and west bring in three times as  much
streamflow  as  originates  within  the study area.  The flat,
low-lying terrane does not offer opportunities  for  extensive
development  of  surface-water  supplies  through  the  use of
reservoirs.  Much of the  surface  water  is  contaminated  by
saltwater  from the ocean.  Ground water occurs in three major
aquifers,  all of which contain both freshwater and saltwater.
(Author)
Descriptors:   *Water resources,  *Surveys,  -"Coastal r
*Hydrology, North Carolina,  Resource management,  Rest
Surface waters,  Salt water,  Contamination,  Aquifers,
water, Flooding, Ocean tides, Ecology, Rivers
Identifiers:  Landscaping,  Evapotranspiration,   Chowan River,
Roanoke River, Tar River, Neuse River, Outer  banks,  *Econornic
development, *Northeast Region(North Carolina),  Precipitat ion-
Meteorology), Stream Mow, Runoff,  Ground water,  Salt water
intrustlon, NTISDODXA

AD-A057 484/SST   NTIS Prices: PC A06/MF 401
                              1-98

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
Water  Resources  Appraisal  for  Hydroelectric Licensing Kern
River Basin, California

Federal Power Commission, Washington, D.C. Bureau of Power.
D2224J3    Fid: 8H, 10A, 48G, 971   GRAI7712
1977   94p
Woni tor:  13

Abstract:  The report presents  information  on  existing  and
possible   future   development  of  water  and  related  land
resources in the Kern River Basin.  The basin is part  of  the
Central Valley in south-central California.

Descriptors:   *Water  resources,  *Kern River Basin,  Natural
resources, Water supply, Geology,  Climate,  Hydrology,  Water
quality,  Land use,  Economic development,  Hydroelectric power
generation, California, Surveys, Reviewing, Licenses

Identifiers: NTISFPC

PB-264 750/1ST   NTIS Prices: PC A05/MF A01
                          1-99

-------
                               HVdroe,ectric Licensing. darlon




         Power Commission,  Washington,  D.C. Bureau of Power.


 Appraisal  rept.
 Monitor:  18
CaS^oanCt^VerThLs^nPt  P^yj v'S,^*  an^

FPC-licensed Plney hydroeleCtr ic Si^.opSnt .
                             n.ater     , i-
Recreation,   Reservoirs    F™     PUt'°n>  ««'"• waters,
development   Keservoirs-  . Economic  conditions,  River basin



Identifiers: NTISFPC



PB-232 186/7   NTIS Prices: PC A04/MF A01
                          1-100

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
  I
  I
  I
  I
Water  Resources Appraisal for Hydroelectric Licensing.  Kings
River Basin, California


Federal Power Commission, Washington, D.C. Bureau of Power.
C3503D4    Fid: 13B, 48B   GRAI7422
Aug 74   82p
Monitor: 18

Aostract: The report on the Kings River Basin,  California,  has
been prepared by the staff of the Federal Power Commission  as
a  part  of  a  program  of  Water  Resources  Appraisals  for
Hydroelectric Licensing.  It is intended primarily to  provide
information  which  the  Commission  and  its staff may use or
build upon,  as appropriate,  when considering matters related
to hydroelectric licensing, relicensing, or recommendation for
Federal  takeover.   Licensing  considerations  are  currently
underway for several projects 'n the Kings River  Basin.    The
report has been preoared to correlate and,  when possible,   to
supplement available information and thus enable the staff and
the Commission to act expeditiously on matters  pertaining  to
the  development  of  the hydroelectric power potential of the
Kings River Basin within the limitations  of  other  desirable
water uses.

Descriptors:    *Water   resources,    *Kings   River   Basin,
*Hydroelectric power generation,   Licenses,   Electric  power
plants, Project planning,  Economic development,  Agriculture,
Recreation,  Water supply,   Appraisals,   Industries,   Flood
control, Irrigation, Pumped storage, Environmental impacts

Identifiers: Specific areas, NTISFPC

PB-235 224/3   NTIS Prices: PC A05/MF A01
                           1-101

-------
Water  Quality  Management Element for the Kentucky River Area
Development District. Comprehensive Water and Sewer Plan

Kentucky Office for Local Government, Frankfort.
C1645F1    Fid: 138, 680   GRAI7321
dun 73   91p
Rept No: CK-OLG-73-37
Project: HUD-CPA-KY-1000
Monitor: 18
                    Sudderth and Etheredge,
Prepared by Mayes,
Ky.
Inc.,   Lexington,
Abstract:   There  are three principal sources of pollution to
the waters of the Kentucky  River:   coal  mining  activities,
untreated  domestic waste,  and municipal plant effluent.  The
report is addressed  to  the  steps  necessary  to  reduce  or
eliminate  pollution  from  these  sources.   In each of these
cases, the lack of definitive data as to the nature and origin
of the pollution is evident.  In order to plan and execute  an
effective  pollution  abatement  program in the Kentucky River
Area Development District, the collection of the basic data i3
necessary.  Alternative methods of municipal sewage  treatment
are covered in this Report. These alternatives include the use
of tertiary lagoons,  where physically possible,  and advanced
tertiary treatment facilities.  The need for additional sewage
collection and treatment facilities is set  forth.
Descriptors: (*Water pollution,
pollution,  Regional planning),
growth,   Coal   mines,    Industrial  wastes,   Sewage
Lagoons(°onds), Economic analysis,  Local  government
                                *Regional  planning)
                                 Water  resources
         (*Stream
       Populat ion
       treatment,
Identifiers:  Kentucky,   Water quality data,
treatment, *Water pollution abatement, UPCD

PB-223 046/4   NTIS Prices: PC E04/MF A01
                                              Tertiary   sewage
                         1-102

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
Water Resources of the Upper Neuse River Basin, North Carolina

Geological Survey, Raleigh, N.C.*Durham City, N.C.


Water-resources investigations rept. (Final)
AUTHOR: Putnam, Arthur L. ;  Lindskov, Kenneth L.
C3931G2    Fid: 138, 8H,  483, 48G   GRAI7502
May 73   78p
Rept No: USGS/WRI-12-73;  USGS/WRD-74-037
Monitor: 18
Prepared in cooperation with Durham City, N.C.


Abstract'-    To  aid  planners  and  developers,   the  report
summarizes data on  duration  of  flow,   low-flow  frequency,
Storage  requirements,   and  flood  frequency.   Data for the
43-year period 1925-68 show that the average annual streamflovn
for the upper Neuse River basin is about 320  million  gallons
per day.  Comparison of this flow with the total withdrawal of
both surface and ground water of 20 million gallons  per  day,
indicates  the  relatively  minor  utilization  of  the  water
resources of the basin.   If  proper  pollution  controls  are
observed  and  practiced  so  that  the  water  in the various
streams may be used a number  of  times,   the  potential  for
water-resources  development and use is more than 10 times the
quantity of water presently used.

Descriptors: *Streamflow, *Neuse River, *Water supply,  *North
Carolina, Water storage,  Floods, Water levels,  Surface waters,
Ground water, Correlation techniques,  Water consumption, Water
pollution,   Water  resources.   Regional  planning,  Economic
development

Identifiers:  Low flow,  Flood frequency,  Water  utilization,
*Water quality data, NTISOIUSGS

PB-237 304/1SL   NTlS Prices: PC A05/MF A01
                           1-103

-------
Water Resources Appraisal for Hydroelectric Licensing,  Winton
Development,  Kawishiwi  River Minnesota

Federal  Power Commission, Washington, O.C. Bureau of Power.

Evaluation rept.
C4241H3    Fid: 138, 97G   GRAI7507
1974   47p .
Rept No: FPC-PWR-469
Moni tor: 18

Abstract:  The water resources appraisal report evaluates  the
Winton  hydroelectric  power  project located on the Kawishiwi
River in Minnesota. Its purpose is to assist the Commission in
deciding  whether  to  relicense  hydroelectric  projects   or
recommend Federal takeover.   It in no way commits or prejudges
later Commission action.

Descriptors:   *Minnesota,  *Electric power plants,  *Kaw)shiwi
River,   Licenses,   Evaluation,   Land development,  Economic

analysts. Hydroelectric  power generation, Water  resources

Identifiers.' *Winton project, Local  studies, NTISFPC

PB-238  963/3ST   NTIS Prices: PC A03/MF A01
                                 1-104

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
Water   Supply  Dilemmas  of  Geothermal  Development  in  the
Imperial Valley of California

California Univ.,  Livenmore.  Lawrence Livermore  Lab.*£nergy
Research and Development Administration.   (9500007)
AUTHOR: Layton, D. W.
D2835E4    Fid: 81, 97P, 971   GRAI7716
15 Sep 76   21p
Rept No: CONF-760990-1
Contract: W-7405-ENG-48
Monitor: 18
12.  American water resources conference,  Chicago,  Illinois,
United States of America (USA), 19 Sep 1976.

Abstract:  There are four known geothermal resource  areas  in
the  Imperial  Valley  that  have a combined potential  of over
4,000 megawatts of electrical energy for 25 years.  The  water
resources  available  to support geothermal energy development
are imported Colorado River water,  agricultural, waste waters,
Salton Sea water,  and ground water.  In addition,  gaothermal
power plants can produce their own cooling water in  the  form
of steam condensate.  Nevertheless,  the relatively high water
requirements of geothermal  facilities along with a  series  of
real and potential constraints may cause water supply dilemmas
involving  both  the  acquisition  and  use  of cooling water.
Important constraints are institutional  policies, water supply
costs,  technical problems,  and impacts upon the Salton  Sea.
These  constraints  and related dilemmas are examined in lignt
of relevant  information  on  the  valley's  water  resources,
geothermal  resources  and energy technologies,  cooling water
requirements,   and  water  supply  options.    (ERA   citation
02'.0261 32)

Descriptors:   *Geothermal   power  plants,   *Imperial  Valley,
California,  Colorado  River,   Cooling  systems,   Economics,
Geothermal   fields,    Ground   water,    Salton  Sea,    Water
requirements, Water resources

Identifiers: ERDA/150200, ERDA/150800, NTISERDA

UCRL-78019   NTIS Prices: PC A02/MF A01
                         1-105

-------
The  Willamette Basin Comprehensive Study of Water and Related
Land Resources. Appendix J. Power
Pacific Northwest River Basins Commission Vancouver  Wash    (
410072)
D1985D1    Fid: 13B, 8H, 48B, 48G   GRAI7711
1969   I05p
Moni tor: 18
Original contains color plates:  All DDC reproductions will be
in black and white.   Appendix J  to  AO-A036   745.   See  also
Appendix K, AD-A036 763.

Abstract:  The purpose of this Appendix is to show the present
power needs and existing generating capacity  in the Willamette
Basin, to determine future power needs,  to identify potential
projects  in  the  basin  which  could  be developed for power
generation,  and to evaluate potential projects  as  to  their
utility for power development. The power potentials within the
basin   are  presented  from  a  single-purpose  viewpoint  to
determine the maxinum extent to which the water resource could
be developed for power generation.  Power requirements,   load
characteristics, interconnections, and power-source potentials
are  projected  to  the  years  1980,  200p,   and 2020.  These
projections   are   the   basis   for   planning   long-range,
comprehensive  water resource development.  The 1980 estimates
provide the basis for development of  a  plan  to  meet  early
power needs of the basin.  The longer-term appraisals are more
conjectural and tentative.

Descriptors:  *Water  resources,   *£nvironmental  management,
Oregon, Reservoirs,  Rivers,  Lakes,  Basins(Geographic),  Land
use,  Planning,  Requirements,  Hydrology,  Economic analysis.
Nuclear power plants

Identifiers:  *Willamette River Basin,  Electric power demand.
Water resources development, NTISDODXA

AD-A036 762/3ST   NTIS Prices: PC A06/MF A01
                                  1-106

-------

         Section 2,Q
RELEVANT PHOTOCOPIED ARTICLES

-------
 I

 I
 _                                       Section 2.0
 •                              RELEVANT PHOTOCOPIED ARTICLES

 •                    Included in this section are photocopies of articles which may
 •          be of particular relevance to EPA officials concerned with socio-economic
             analysis of Chesapeake Bay water resources.  No claim is made that these
 I          articles exhaust the supply of relevant literature.  Instead, they are
             intended to convey a flavor for the range and quality of analysis available
 I          in current literature.
 •                    The articles are categorized as in the first section:  economic
             analysis; socio-political analysis; methodology; and environmental case
 I          studies.  Each article appears once under the heading selected as most
             appropriate.


 I

 I
                                                                   *
 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

I

I
•

-------
2.1  Alphabetical Listing of Economic Analysis Articles
 1.  An Approach to Evaluating Environmental,  Social,  and Economic Factors
     in Water Resources Planning.
 2.  Approaches to Multiobjective  Planning in  Water Resource Projects.
 3.  Economic Forecasting for Virginia's Water Resource Programs.
 4.  Economic Valuation of Shoreline.
 5.  Economics.  (L.D.  James, Georgia Institute of Technology).
 6.  Economics.  (L.D.  James, Utah State University).
 7.  Economics.  (J.C.  Hite, Clemson University and L.D.  James,  Utah
     Water Resources Laboratory).
 8.  Economics and the  Environment.
 9.  The Efficiency and Equity of  Cost Allocation Methods for Multipurpose
     Water Projects.
10.  Metarationality in Benefit-Cost Analyses.
11.  Socio-Economlc Considerations in Water Resources  Planning.
12.  Water Resource Investment and Economic Development:   Balanced Versus
     Unbalanced Investment Strategies.
                                    2-2

-------
I
I
              2.2  Economic Analysis Articles
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
                                                2-3
I

-------
                           WATER RESOURCES BULLETIN
VOL. 8, NO. 4         AMERICAN WATER RESOURCES ASSOCIATION          AUGUST 1972
           AN APPROACH  TO  EVALUATING ENVIRONMENTAL, SOCIAL,
           AND ECONOMIC FACTORS IN WATER RESOURCES PLANNING1

                                   A. Bruce Bishop2
   ABSTRACT. Decisions among water resources planning alternatives must consider, along with engi-
   neering and economics, a variety of environmental and social effects which are viewed and weighted
   differently by  different  interest groups. This paper briefly discusses present methods of project
   evaluation and  then describes an approach adapted from highway planning literature for evaluating
   both monetary and non-monetary variables and presenting  them  to decision  makers at all levels.
   Social and environmental consequences are analyzed and presented using a graphical  description
   called a "factor profile," which measures in appropriate units all relevant non-monetary effects of
   each alternative. Then, using the factor profile and engineering-economic analysis, a senes of paired
   comparisons  are made to obtain a preference ranking among alternatives. Since preference decisions
   are  extremely  complex, a  step by  step procedure  to simplify the decision-making process is
   described. A case example considering four proposed flood control alternatives with the relevant
   environmental and social impacts is given to illustrate  the use of the factor profile and the decision
   making procedure.
   (KEY TERMS, planning; decision making, project evaluation; environmental impacts; social aspects;
   economic analysis)
                           INTRODUCTION

   Water  resources development has a wide  range of  impacts on the various users, on the
surrounding communities, and on  the  region and nation as a whole. Moreover, these conse-
quences intersect  a broad range of economic, social, environmental, and community values
which are viewed and weighted  differently by different interest groups. Hence, choices and
tradeoffs  must be made to achieve the highest  satisfaction of public wants.  Unfortunately,
there is no effective market mechanism to allocate resources for public wants as there is for
the private sector of the economy. Consequently,  other means  must be  found to induce
various segments of the public to  reveal their preferences for public goods. At the national
level this  is accomplished by Congress  through the political process. However, at the level of
comprehensive planning for river basins or specific projects, this must be achieved by planners
interacting with  the  public  through the  planning  process.  In this setting, water resources
planning becomes a process of refining  and choosing among alternative approaches for satisfy-
ing public wants, evaluating them on the basis of their social, environmental, and community
feasibility as well as for engineering and economics.
   'Paper No. 72067 of the Water Resources Bulletin Discussions are open until January 1, 1973.
   'Assistant  Professor of Civil Engineering,  Utah Water Research  Laboratory, Utah State University,
Logan, Utah 84321.


                                          724
                                              2-4

-------
I
I
I
1
i
I
I
ff
I
I
I
I
i
i
i
i
i
I
i
     APPROACH TO EVALUATING ENVIRONMENTAL, SOCIAL. AND ECONOMIC FACTORS  725


          WATER RESOURCES, NEEDS, AND PLANNING  ALTERNATIVES


   The problem of the water resources planner is illustrated by the diagram of Figure  1. We

have at our disposal a set of limited resources with which to satisfy our needs. As the diagram
shows, the aggregate  of all our needs will  usually  exceed the  capability  of our resources.
Generally, within  the  limits of our resources, there will be  sets of alternatives which are feasi-
ble from the standpoint of technological and economic considerations, but may not satisfy
social, environmental, and political values, and vice versa. To  use the language of set theory,
the job of the water resources planner is to find that subset of alternatives which is the inter-

section (the  darkest area of Figure 1)  of all the feasible (economically, socially, etc.) sets of

alternatives. These are alternatives which could be implemented.
                                                 1-ENVIRONMENTAL

                                                 2-ECONOMICAL

                                                 3-POLITICAL

                                                 4-SOCIAL

                                                 5-ENGINEERING/TECHNICAL FEASIBILITY

                                                 6-RESOURCES

                                                 7-NEEDS
                    Fig. 1. Limits of feasibility in water resources planning.
                                           2-5

-------
726                                A. Bruce Bishop

   The usual approach in water resources planning is to develop a set of technologically feasi-
ble alternatives and then to complete the planning effort by determining economic feasibility.
The limits of social, environmental, and  political feasibility, while not entirely ignored, are
largely left to others to be determined after the plan is complete. More often than not these
missing ingredients are the ultimate cause of planning failures.  For example, some of the
broad issues  and questions which must be considered in refining the limits for our sets of
feasible alternatives are:
   Technological/environmental. The technological impact of a completed public work, con-
structed and in  place, represents a definite change in the environment which  is difficult to
reverse. It is  often literally set down in  concrete. Since it represents a permanent change, it is
important to consider whether or not this kind of physical change should be made at all, and
if it is made, should it be made now and in this particular way.
   Economic. The costs and benefits of public works are generally distributed among many
different interest groups. Construction of a dam or flood control works brings about changes
in  land use, dislocation of people and property, and alterations in living patterns, all of which
serve to redistribute economic resources. In evaluating the impact of public works, one can no
longer just assess the benefits "to whomsoever they accrue," but in addition, it must be deter-
mined who receives the benefits and who incurs the costs.
   Social.  Public works tend to have the nature of self-fulfilling social prophecies. If projects
are built they will become part of the fabric of an area, and the products from construction of
a new dam will cause changes in the social  structure,  environment, population, and living
patterns of the  region, which  are  responsible, at least in part,  for creating the needs  and
demands that the project purposes intend to satisfy. Since projects generate  a certain amount
of social  self-fulfillment,  it is  important to  ask: What would realistically be expected to
happen if the project were not  built? In asking this question we must recognize that "doing
nothing" is a viable  alternative, and that it is a dynamic and not a status quo condition.
   Political. There is rarely a single decision maker in public works planning,  and decisions are
made difficult because  of the number of interactions among potential decision makers. The
planners' success depends on his recognition of which interest groups can and should influence
the plans,  how and by whom the final  decision is made, how to translate technical data into
public policy issues and test them politically, and how to make public participation in plan-
ning a meaningful activity.
   With the broadening public interest in  water resources, planners must recognize  that envi-
ronmental, social, and political feasibility are  as essential a part of the planning process as
engineering and economics. Hence,  the planner should refine the  limits of social and political
feasibility   along  with  engineering and  economics  throughout the entire planning process.
Referring  to  Figure 1, it appears that much of the earlier technical stages of planning may be
of only marginal concern in relation to the  end product that can be implemented. Indeed,
large amounts of time and resources may be spent  in developing plans that are  outside the
limits of feasibility  in one area  or another.
   In some cases  we may find in  fact that there are feasibility sets which do not intersect at
all. It is important to point out, however, that the areas of social and political feasibility do
not  necessarily have fixed  predetermined limits. They  depend to a significant extent upon
clear understanding of the possibilities and the range of choices. The key to realistic appraisal
of environmental, social, and political feasibility is to maintain constant communication with
a broad spectrum of those who  will finally determine  these limits. If the planner  begins to
bracket these ranges of feasibility early in the study, then more of the planning efforts can be
confined  to  the subset of plans which  is  more likely to be  acceptable. Thus,  adequate
                                          2-6

-------
I
I
t
1
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
t
I
I
t
     APPROACH TO EVALUATING ENVIRONMENTAL, SOCIAL. AND ECONOMIC FACTORS   727

interchange of information can serve both as a means to establish the feasibility limits and as a
guide to avoid marginal effort.

                     EVALUATING WATER RESOURCES PLANS

   In the evaluation of water resources plans, the practice has been to aggregate the informa-
tion  relevant  to the decision which could be quantified in economic terms into a benefit-cost
ratio. However, such consequences as environmental, social aesthetic, and community impacts
have not been included in the benefit-cost ratio since neither suitable techniques nor adequate
data have been available for appraising  and quantifying them. Furthermore, in many cases it
may be  inappropriate  to quantify them in  money terms. It follows that a  discussion and
evaluation of alternatives based solely on the  benefit-cost ratio will often submerge or exclude
information  that is  pertinent to the  decision.  It tends to obscure  rather than  pinpoint the
differences among alternatives and leaves no  way to identify and contrast these differences in
decision making.
   Recently  a special  task force of the Water Resources Council has sought to expand the
basis for comparing alternative plans by outlining four "accounts" for evaluation of water and
related land  resource projects. These include (1) national income, (2) regional development,
(3) environmental enhancement, and (4) social well-being. Test teams from several universities
and Federal water planning agencies attempted to apply this system of evaluation to a number
of current projects. While in most cases  national income and regional development benefits
and costs were given adequate treatment, the environmental and social well-being effects were
generally given only cursory and elementary attention. In reviewing the experience of the test
teams  there  are two  particular  areas of need in approaching project  evaluation  [Water
Resources Council, 1970]:
    (1) Procedures for communicating project  impacts to the public to elicit their input
        in formulating project objectives and evaluating project product outputs.
    (2) Procedures for making tradeoffs among various objectives of the four accounts.
   These findings underscore  the need for  methods  to describe,  analyze,  and  present to
decision  makers the principal social, environmental, and community variables in water re-
sources plans. Furthermore,  our approaches to plan evaluation should allow each community
and interest group  to examine the proposed plans and determine the consequences and trade-
offs  as seen  from their particular viewpoint so that they can be considered  in the decision
making process. To accomplish these aims, a basis must be established for evaluating and com-
municating both monetary and non-monetary consequences. To do this two important rules,
which  have  often  been ignored in  evaluation schemes, must be kept in mind [Grant and
Ireson, 1964]:
    (1) The decisions must be based on the differences among alternatives.
    (2) _TKat money consequences must be separated from the consequences that are not
        reducible to money terms; then these  irreducibles must be weighed against the
        money consequences as part of the  decision making process.
To apply these rules in an engineering, economic, environmental, and social analysis of the
effects of water resources  development, four important aspects of the  problem should be
considered. These are:
   (a) Identification of factors relevant to the decision. Planning experience has shown that it
is often difficult for groups  to identify or express their objectives at the inception of a study.
However, a strong program  of citizen participation  and the use of survey research techniques
can provide needed  input for defining an initial  set  of planning objectives. Then as alternative
                                          2-7

-------
728                                A. Bruce BiOiop

plans are developed, sets of objectives are seen in terms of their physical and functional form.
This can then  serve as a basis for evaluating and reformulating objectives, and can also suggest
factors (dimensions) to measure and quantify the impact of alternative plans on the planning
objectives.
   (b) Quantification. Comparisons of the differences among alternatives depend on defining
the factors which measure the relative merits of the plans. The factors relevant to the decision
should be separated into those direct consequences that can be stated in economic money
terms at both  the regional and national level and those environmental and social effects which
fall upon the  communities which  are not an  appropriate part of the economic  costs and
benefits. Where possible, and there exists a rationale for doing so, these non-monetary factors
should be measured and evaluated in some other appropriate unit. Then, monetary and other
factors can be  weighted against each other to determine the tradeoffs among alternatives.
   (c) Viewpoint. Different alternatives affect the various levels of government, communities,
and groups in  different ways. Much of today's controversy in water planning and management
results from the failure of one group to appreciate another's values and concerns. The factors
which are most important  will,  of course,  vary with each  individual  project. Various
approaches to  public participation should be used at the conceptual stage  of plan formulation
and  again during plan  evaluation to allow each group to express  its  principal concerns. By
identifying the factors of greatest concern to each community group, the i_osts and benefits
and  the points of agreement and disagreement can be clarified. Consideration of varying view-
points should  eliminate confusion and many of the pointless arguments which now afflict
planning studies.
   (d) Time period. The time period over which the consequences of various plans are spread
should  also be considered. Otherwise short-run effects might be given more weight in the
decision as compared to the long-run effects,  or vice versa.
   In developing dimensions for the description of alternatives,  it should be emphasized that
both the viewpoint and the time period or horizon will markedly affect the analysis in select-
ing and quantifying the relevant factors  in decision making. These need to be specified before
variables are quantified, and  indeed  a  complete evaluation may require that a number of
analyses be performed using different viewpoints and planning horizons.

A Method for Presenting and Evaluating
Water Planning Alternatives

   Following from the  two decision rules stated earlier, a two-part procedure is Necessary to
objectively present and evaluate alternatives: (1) an economy study which includes all items
that can be reduced to money terms, and (2) an  analysis of all items which cannot be stated in
terms of money but which must be weighed in the decision.  Recent efforts have been made to
develop new  methods and  techniques  which apply these  principles  in  evaluating planning
alternatives.
   A procedure  for decision making among freeway route location alternatives has been pro-
posed by Bishop [1969]  and Oglesby, Bishop, and Willeke [1970]. This approach, called a
"factor profile," is a method for  analyzing, presenting, and comparing the indirect, environ-
mental, social  and community effects with the economic effects of alternative highway plans.
It  appears that the use of such tools can be a valuable step  toward a more rational discussion
of and decisions among alternatives based on  economic, social, and environmental factors in
water  resources planning as  well as transportation planning. The  following  section of this
paper applies the concept of the "factor profile," to water resources plan evaluation, describes
                                           2-8

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
fi
I
I
t
I
I
f
      APPROACH TO EVALUATING ENVIRONMENTAL, SOCIAL, AND ECONOMIC FACTORS  729

the procedure for using it, and  presents  an example problem.  The  discussion ana example
closely  parallel that for the highway location alternatives in order to emphasize the similarities
between evaluation of transportation and water resources projects.

Factor Profiles: A Decision Making Tjol

   The  "factor profile" is a graphical representation based on the factors which describe by
some appropriate unit  of measure the effects of each proposed alternative. Figure 2 is a highly
simplified  and consolidated version of such  a profile for four  flood control alternatives,
numbered  1, 2,  3,  and 4. On this  figure, each profile scale is on a percentage base,  ranging
from a  negative to a positive 100 percent. One hundred either negative or positive is the maxi-
mum absolute value  of the measure that is adopted for each factor. Reduction to the percent-
age base simplifies scaling and plotting the profiles. The maximum positive or negative value
of the measure, the units, and the time span are indicated on the right-hand side of the profil?
for reference. For each alternative, the positive  or negative value for any factor is calculated as
a percent of the  maximum  absolute value over all alternatives and is plotted on the appropri-
ate abscissa. A broken  line connecting  the plotted points for each alternative gives its factor
profile.  For the profiles,  factors  and measures should  be selected  which  will  adequately
describe all important elements of community and environmental impact. Care should  be used
in defining factor  measures to assure  that  they  are not measuring the same consequences.
Otherwise  in effect there  would be  "double counting" and disproportionate weight would be
given to those factors. This may result in incorrect preference decisions.
       FWTM
                                       PE IttIT EFFECT
                                                                         HAItt* POSITIVE ff) KUTM
                                                                          MUK m MY W.1EMWW
                                                                        WlUC    MIS TIC SM, IK
   lOCAl IIICIIIATIONAl
     OP"0*TUNITIII
    GRfEMUTVOU
     1CWC1HG •*
    WI«IM •* HIDING
       THAK1
  LAW USE — OtVI lOPAI
    UMO  LA«0 IN
      HQOOtAIN
    CBMtWWTV IMPACT
   IMUlVUWTSOtffUCtO
      IY PltlJJf CT
     COMTHUCTION
   CONVUNITV f ACUITIES
   CHURCHES C«HW*TY
 CfRTf tS UMOOll MOSPITAU
    •EGIOMIICOWWY
   MMKIAl AflO IMtOTOIAl
    MOKfTVOISFLACCg
    KMCCTMTAItAH
    [AlKSftO VALUf Of
    MOHITVTAIfm
(<) 10,000
USER
DAYS
               5-15
 «•) 400   ACRES    S-20
 -"<«   LSsG   »•»
 (-) S  FACILITIES  0-5
 H U   PARCELS/   ..5
      FACILITIES
l-l'il  MILLION   0-K
                       Fig. 2. Factor profiles for flood control alternatives.
                                              2-9

-------
730                                 A. Bruce Bishop

   In order to  reduce  the complexity  of the diagram  and, m turn,  of the decision making
process, the full set of factors should be  reduced whenever it is possible to do bo  Two guide-
lines are suggested for accomplishing this:  (1) eliminating all those factors that are not relevant
or important to the particular decision,  and (2) eliminating all factors where the values are
substantially the same for all alternatives. These tests must be acceptable to all parties involved
in the study.
   It is expected that the profiles will be prepared for each alternative from the viewpoint of
each community  interest group and will incorporate  the  factors  that are  important to that
particular group's viewpoint. A composite profile would  also be prepared showing the  total
community effect for  each  factor.  Separate profiles for  each  alternative could be made on
transparent overlays to facilitate  the  method  of comparison proposed  in  the following
paragraphs. In passing it should be noted that research is  also under way to provide such dis-
plays on a cathode-ray tube  activated by  a computer. This would permit almost instant recall
of any comparisons  that seemed appropriate.

Method for Plan Evaluation

   Because  of the complexity that "real  life" factor profiles would often have,  a systematic
procedure  for evaluating and comparing the  relative merits of the several alternatives is essen-
tial. The method proposed here is that  a series of paired comparisons be made using engineer-
ing economic analysis and factor profiles as the decision  making  tools.
   First,  alternatives 1  and 2 are compared:  then the better of these is compared with 3. and
so on. In  comparing two alternatives  the incremental cost or benefit  from the economic
analysis is weighed against the differences in community and environmental impact  between
the alternatives as shown by the factor profiles. The decision maker representing each group
would  appraise the  economic  and community factors  and determine  his preference  between
the two alternatives. After  all the paired comparisons among the various  alternatives  have
been completed, there would result preference rankings  for each viewpoint in the community.
These  would  be used for  comparisons  among competing  viewpoints  in  reaching a  final
decision.
   From the point of view of the science of decision theorv. the paired comparison approach
falls down when more  than  two parties are involved in the decision. Hosvever,  this theoretical
objection does not mean the  paired comparison approach will not work in the real world. This
difficulty is widely discussed  in the literature  [Luce and  Raiffa.  1957].
   A highly simplified  example to illustrate  the paired comparison approach  is given by the
question.  "Is it preferable to  save S50.000 per  year in flood damages accruing to local resi-
dents by adopting a bypass flood routing or to dislocate a commercial enterprise situated in
the bypass which employs  ten people  and paying S20.000 per year in property taxes? It is
estimated  that  a substitute  enterprise  will  develop in five years."  It is admitted that tins
example  is far  simpler than  those of the real world where the factor profile would include
several elements.  Even so, such comparisons make clear  the actual points at issue and may
greatly  reduce the  number of irrational  arguments  that accompany  most controversial
decisions.
   The flow chart of Figure  3 depicts the  procedure to be followed in making the paired com-
parisons just described. Such a procedure should greatly help community groups  and  decision
makers in selecting a preferred alternative.
   Step 1: Perform  Engineering Economic Analysis.  Rank  the alternatives in order of prefer-
ence as determined  by  the economic analysis. This may be done on the basis of maximum net
                                           2-10

-------
 I
 I
 i
 i
 i
 i
 i
 i
 i
 i
 i
 s
 §
 i
 i
 i
 i
I
t
     APPROACH TO EVALUATING ENVIRONMENTAL, SOCIAL,  AND ECONOMIC FACTORS   73 1


benefits over cost or total and  incremental benefit cost ratios or rates of return. Tabulate the
net benefits over costs for each  alternative.

   Step 2. Prepare Factor Profiles. Factor profiles are prepared from  the viewpoint of each

interest group showing the plan or project's  impact  on each relevant factor for that group.

A factor profile is also prepared which  shows the total  or aggregate effect of each alternative
over all communities  and groups.

   Step 3: Economic and Factor Profile Analysis.  Compare alternatives on  the basis  of the

economic analysis ajid  the  factor  profiles. Eliminate any alternative which is dominated  by

another from  the standpoint  of  both  the  economic analysis  and  the  factor profile. One

alternative strictly  dominates another if  all percentage  values of the  factor profile of that
                                         ANALYSIS OF ALTERNATIVES
                                              '<,», Z )
                                        OBTAIN OATA ON FACTORS TO
                                         8E USED IN THE ANALYSIS
                                 DIRECT
                                                            INDIRECT
                       STEP (I!
                          "ERFORM ENGINEERING-
                           ECONOMIC ANALYSIS

STEP (2)

'REPARATION OF
FACTOR PROFILES
                          CALCULATE'NCREMENTAL
                          NET BENEFITS (COSTS)
                           RANK ALTERNATIVES
                              (X.Y.Z)
                                   STEP (3)
                                   ECONOMIC AND FACTOR PROFILE ANALYSIS
                                    IS ALTERNATIVE DOMINATED BY ANOTHER
                                      BOTH IN ECONOMIC  ANALYSIS AND
                                           fACTOR PROFILE '
                                   STEP (4)
YES
                                                  NO
                                     PAIRED COMPARISONS OF ALTERNATIVES
                                               (X,Y)
                                     DETERMINE INCREMENTAL DIFFERENCES
                                      IN FACTOR  PROFILES BETWEEN PAIR
                                               -4-
                                          PREFERENCE DECISION
                                          IS X>Y  OR  Y>X '
                                              (X>Y)
                                      CHECK AGAINST ECONOMIC ANALYSIS
                                     RANKING  IS PREFERRED ALTERNATIVE
                                     ALSO PREFERRED IN ECONOMIC STUOf
                                      TRADEOFF WITH INCREMENTAL COSTS
                                      (BENEFITS) ARE GAINS (LOSSES)
                                       IN COMMUNITY FACTORS WORTH
                                      ADDITIONAL (INCREMENTAL) COSTS
                                             (BENEFITS)'
                          Fig. 3.  Flow chart for analysis of alternatives.
                                                2-11

-------
732                                A. Bruce Bishop

alternative are greater than that of the other. This implies that there are no crossovers in the
lines of the factor profiles for the two.
   Step 4: Paired Comparisons of Alternatives. Paired comparisons are made for each view-
point on the basis of the incremental differences in community effects from the  factor pro-
files,  and comparing these  with  the incremental differences in costs from the  economic
analysis.  Any two alternatives can be paired, but a reasonable beginning would be  to pair one
of  the  alternatives having a  good  factor  profile with the preferred alternative from the
economic analysis.
   (a) Determine the differences between  the alternatives  for  the community  and environ-
mental factors, and  compare  the increments of values gained with the increments of values
lost.
   (b) State  a preference between the two alternatives based  on the importance to the decision
makers of the tradeoffs among the factors.
   (c) Check the preference statement against the ranking  from the economic analysis. This
resolves the  question, "Is the alternative  preferred in (b) also superior from the standpoint of
the economic analysis?" If the answer is "yes" then  the prefened  alternatives is paired with
the next  alternative selected for analysis. If "no," then the analysis proceeds to (d).
   (d) Test  the  differences  in community and environmental  factors against the excess  of
costs  over benefits. The decision maker is asking the question. "Are the gains in these  factors
worth the additional incremental costs of this alternative?"  If the answer is "yes" the alterna-
tive of higher cost is preferred because of its higher community and environmental benefits.
Otherwise, the alternative preferred from the economic analysis is selected and paired  against
the next  alternative for analysis.
   Step 5: Continue Paired Comparison Procedure. The procedure (a) through (d) is continued
until  all  feasible alternatives  have  been included in comparisons. The paired comparisons
among the feasible alternatives produce a preferred alternative, and also a  preference ranking
among all alternatives for each viewpoint if this is desired.
   The only constraint imposed on the decision makers in  the paired comparisons  is that
preferences among alternatives must be  transitive, i.e., if A is preferred to B, and B is preferred
to C, then A is preferred to C. This  insures that preferences and decisions are consistent with
previous  ones, and  that  the  final ranking  of alternatives reflects  the  decision  makers' true
preferences.
   In sum, the purpose of the factor profiles and the procedure  for analysis is to help the
decision  maker apply the two basic  principles of decision making: (1) to  separate economic
effects measurable in dollar values from other consequences, and (2) to compare  the differ-
ences in  alternatives  in making decisions. The factor profiles and the method of analysis offer
both a visual aid and a systematic procedure for implementing these principles. The construc-
tion of the factor profiles does not  imply that the area under the curves can be integrated, or
the percentage values of factors can be added in order to make a decision.

An Example Application

   Consider  four proposed flood control alternatives with the relevant community and envi-
ronmental impact factors and corresponding factor profiles depicted  in Figure 2. An analysis
of  the economic costs and benefits of the alternatives is  given in Table  1. The  economic
analysis indicates that alternative 2 is preferred, since  it shows a benefit-cost ratio greater than
1 on  the total investment and on all increments of investment. Alternative 1 ranks next, then
4 and 3 have equal desirability from an economic standpoint.
                                            2-12

-------
 I
 I
 i
 I
 I
 I
 i
 i
 i
 i
 i
 i
 t
 5
 I
 I
 I
 I
t
     APPROACH TO EVALUATING ENVIRONMENTAL, SOCIAL. AND ECONOMIC FACTORS   733

                  TABLE 1. Economic Analysis of Flood Control Alternatives

                                                   Alternative
                                                S (in  thousands)
Item
Annual Cost
Annual Average Savings in
Flood Damages
Net Benefits
Benefit-Cost Ratio
1
650
1,000
350
1.54
2
750
1,200
450
1.60
3
850
1,150
300
1.35
4
700
1,000
300
1.43
Incremental Analysis
4 over I
2 over 1
3 over 1
2 over 4
3 over 4
3 over 2
Incremer
Cost
50
100
200
50
150
100
tal
Benefit
0
200
150
200
150
(50)
B/C
Ratio
0
+2.0
+0.75
+4.0
+ 1.0
-0.5
Increm. Net
Bnft. (cost)
(50)
100
(50)
150
0
1150)
   It must be recognized that the rankings given by this analysis can be changed substantially
by changing thejnterest rate, with lower rates tending  to favor higher capital investments.
This example is based on an  interest rate that reflects the minimum attractive rate of return
for a particular planning agency.
   In examining the factor profiles, we find  that the profile of alternate 4 dominates both 1
and 3. Since 4 is equally attractive as 3 in the economic analysis, alternative 3 can be dropped
on the basis of the dominance tests. For the first paired  comparison, alternative 2. preferred
from the economic analysis, is paired  with 4, a dominant alternative from the factor profiles.
In comparing the differences between these  two alternatives, we find that alternative  2  pro-
vides 200 acres of developable land and saves 290 housing units and S.58 million in assessed
valuation. On the other hand, alternative 4 increases the average recreational opportunities in
the community by 500 user days and saves 25 parcels of industrial property and 2 community
facilities. Let it then be assumed that the  decision makers agree that alternative 4 is the more
attractive of the two, based on the factor analysis tradeoffs.
   However, in  the economic analysis alternative 2 is preferred to 4 by $150,000 per year, so
that  additional comparison to the net benefits foregone must also be made. Here it should be
noted that alternative 2 costs  the agency that will build the project 550,000 more per year; on
the other hand, flood  damage costs are $200,000 per year less. It could be that the various
groups would therefore weigh the economic consequences quite differently. Assuming that.
even with the cost differences, alternative  4  is selected over 2, a similar comparison would be
made between 4 and  1.
                                              2-13

-------
734                                 A. Bruce Bishop   ,

                                      SUMMARY

   To summarize, the advantages of the factor analysis method of evaluation are as follows:
   (1)  It separates  the direct money consequences from the social and environmental conse-
quences so that they do not become confused in the analysis;
   (2) In complex decision making where  it is important to have  more rather than less infor-
mation  on which to base the  decisions, it provides a  visual means by which to display the
different factors relevant to making choices;
   (3) It provides a means for comparing the incremental differences in environmental and
social factors among alternatives, and contrasting them with the differences in economic costs
or benefits;
   (4) The analysis also provides for separation of viewpoints as well as an analysis of the
overall impact. It shows the incidence of community effects upon community groups, brings
out the points of agreement or disagreement among those groups, and serves as a mechanism
in resolving those conflicts;
   (5) Finally, factor identification and factor profiles can be a useful tool during the planning
process (a) in defining the factors  which are important  to  the community arid community
groups, (b) in establishing goals and objectives, (c) as a basis for discussion during the develop-
ment of alternatives, and (d)  as a means  of evaluating and making decisions among alterna-
tives.

                                      REFERENCES

Bishop, A. B. 1969. Socio-economic and community factors in planning urban freeways. EEP Report No.
   33, Stanford Program on Engineering Economic Planning, Stanford University, Stanford, California.
Grant, E. L. and W. G. Ireson. 1964.  Principles of engineering economy. Ronald Press, N.Y. 4th ed.
   pp. 21-23, 436, 445-448, 456.
Oglesby, C.  H., A. B. Bishop, and  G. E. Willeke. 1970. A method for decisions among freeway location
   alternatives based  on user and  community consequences  Highway Research Board Record No. 305.
   Washington, D.C. pp. 1-15.
Luce, R. D. and H. Raiffa.  1957. Games and decisions. John Wiley and Sons.
Water Resources Council, Special Task Force.  1970. A summary analysis of  nineteen tests of proposed
   evaluation procedures on selected water and land resource projects. Washington, D.C.
                                           2-14

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
t
 I
 I
 1
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 1
 I
 t
                        WATER RESOURCES BULLETIN

VOL  11. NO 5       AMERICAN WATER RESOURCES ASSOCATION       OCTOBER 1975
           APPROACHES TO MULTIOBJECTIVE PLANNING

                   IN WATER  RESOURCE PROJECTS1


            Bernard W.  Tavlnr. III. K  Rowoe Davis and Ronald M. \orth
                                INTRODKT10N'


   Recently there has been increasing criticism of economic evaluations performed by

 •uter resource agencies  Critics argue that benefit-cost analyses performed by the Corps

 if Engineers.  Tennessee Valley Authority, etc..  do not  reflect  a  true valuation  of

 •nwonmental and  social  objectives. Some  critics further  charge  that water resource

 ^encies do not consider multiple objectives at all and are self-seeking in their economic

 .••dilations. This latter charge, however, may be somewhat  erroneous. It is the authors'

   "inion that water resource agencies have attempted to include environmental and social

   hectives in  the evaluation process but' have, in  general, not  performed  the task very

   -sssfully. The problem that exists is the method of evaluation employed in attempting

    include multiple  objectives. Benefit-cost analysis as currently  implemented  is too

   '"ited to accomodate the complexities presented by a multiple objective approach to

   -'sr resource development.

    Realise of limitations  of benefit-cost analysis, researchers in the  management and

    -;jl sciences have  sought alternative approaches to water resource evaluation. It is the
   •'oos,; of this article to review several alternatives and discuss advantages and limitations

    ;jl-h. These alternatives can be categorized into two areas' mathematical programming

    • '^liie determination methods. In the mathematical programming area, two techniques

      ~v reviewed, goal programming and  the  surrogate worth trade off method. In the

    •''- ^termination  area,  Environmental  Evaluation  Systems (EES) and personal value
    "r"unation will be reviewed. While these methodologies are not all inclusive, they do

     "-
-------
                          Approaches to Multiobjective Planning

evolution of benefit-cost analysis will be presented to provide a better unde-
the need for an alternative evaluation approach.                             Jn - ,
   The origins of benefit-cost analysis and its use in governmental processes ti-
the River  and Harbor  Act  of  1902 (Hammond,  1966).  This  government  ['"""
required the U.S. Army Corps of Engineers to evaluate tangible benefits and  < -'  "
would result  from  navigation projects. The  evaluation process resulted m tri   *
computation of benefit-cost ratios for water resource projects.
   The  Flood  Control  Act  of  1936 formalized  the concepts  of water
development and explicitly stated that ".. . benefits be in excess of costs.  ." (Or  ' '
resource project (Eckstein,  1958). This criterion  can be operatiorialized vi""
alternative benefit-cost algorithms:  the  net present value, internal rate of return
benefit-cost ratio. The  latter technique, the benefit-cost ratio,  has become th
popular and most frequently employed.
   Through practice and legislation, benefit-cost analysis was extended to water res.
projects other than  flood control. Popularity of the technique increased to the pou,i •-
it  was applied also in  other  public areas such as highway  development  and s-in; .
(Margolis, 1959). The increased demand for public goods that private investment
not  supply, in  conjuction  with  the  general expansion  of the concepts  of  we.-
economics, supported evolution of the analysis. Thus, benefit-cost analysis evolved ,H
period  of  years so  that  it  became  ingrained  in  the  water  resources developr.-
decision-making process.
   Within the benefit-cost framework, the  economic  efficiency of a  water res»u:
project  became  the  sole criterion  for  evaluating  and selecting projects.  The nature
analyzed benefits and costs were such that an economic value could be assigned with \\\-
difficulty  and with a certain degree  of justification.  However, the increased PL!-..
awareness of environmental and social factors resulted in the development of  a "mulii:,-
objective planning framework" In  1970 the  Water Resources Council suggested that -,>.
principles  and  standards specified  in previous  government documentation  incli...
environmental  and  social  enhancement and  regional  economic  development (I ••
Government, 1970). The objectives of water resource development were'
  1)   To enhance national economic development by increasing the value of the natu.r
       output of goods and services and improving national economic efficiency;
  2)
  3)
      To enhance  the  quality of the environment by  the management, conservator
      preservation, creation,  restoration  or improvement  of the quality of certaL-
      natural and cultural resources and ecological systems in the  area under study a".
      elsewhere in the nation;
      To enhance social  well-being  by the equitable distribution of  real income
      employment,  and population  with special  concern for the  incidence of iht
      consequences of a plan on affected persons or groups, by providing educational
      cultural, and recreational opportunities;
  4)  To enhance regional development  through  increases in  the values  of a region •
      income,  increases in  employment, and  improvements in its economic  ba^.1
      environemtn, social  well-being,  and other specified  components of the rregion:1
      development objectives.
   In  1973, when new principles and  standards, were finally approved, water resoma-
development was limited to the first two objectives: national economic development arni
                                       2-16

-------
 I
 I
 I
 1
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 1
 I
 1
I
I
1001                           Taylor. Davis and North

enhancement of the environment (U.S. Government. 1973)
  The  economic evaluation of benefits and costs resulting from the multiple objective
.iporoach has proven quite difficult. It is not so simple a  task to place a dollar value on
•ecreation and water quality as is, to a degree, the task of placing a value on navigation
and flood control benefits. In  addition, there are considerations which environmentalists
(supported by the National Environmental Policy Act of 1%9) claim cannot be valued at
ill
  Thus, controversies which have resulted between government water resource agencies
Hid environmentalists  are  not totally a result of an  agency's lack  of consideration of
:nvironmental objectives. The problem,  as  has  been noted,  is one of a new multiple
 objective approach being forced into  a  limited, outdated and generally  incompatible
 .-.•onorrac framework.

      ALTERNATIVE APPROACHES TO WATER RESOURCE EVALUATION

   The  following overview of  some of the more viable alternatives for evaluating water
 •^source projects is divided into two  areas:  mathematical programming techniques and
 •^hodologies  which attempt to  quantify  environmental value outside  an economic
  •amework. Goal programming and the surrogate worth trade off method are included in
  ~£ mathematical  programming  area.  The environmental valuation approaches include
  "nvironmental Evaluation Systems (EES) and personal value determination.

  "^Programming
    There is a scarcity of solution approaches  which can accommodate multiple objectives.
   ^ exists primarily because most mathematical solution methodologies employ a single
   "icctwe function. Goal programming (Chames and Cooper, 1961: Mao, 1969;  Lee,
   '  -), an extension of linear and integer programming, however, is capable of considering
    -iiple goals in the objective function. A goal programming framework, thus, allows the
    "^deration of both economic and environmental objectives.
     'ne goal programming problem is formulated as follows:

               k
     riimae Z =   2 (Wj y+ H- Vj yp
             i= 1
             yi=gi
      M   -
            an objective function,
            a deviational variable measuring the amount of over-attainment of the goal.
            a deviational variable measuring the amount of under-attainment of the goal,
            'he goal attainment desired for objective function i,
            lhe relative weight or penalty cost for over-attainment, and
                                        2-17

-------
                          Approaches to Multiobjective Planning


   Vj      = the relative weight or penalty cost for under-attainment
   The objective function is interpreted  as the minimization of trp i
 desired goals. By weighting the over-attainment and under-attainni '^'>~''
 penalty  cost, it is  possible to economically quantify the magmtuch   • ''  ' '
 Policy decisions are necessary to define the desired goal levels, g.t a,^ (L  """' -
 weights Wj and v^. Original objective functions are transformed into con
 by allowing for under- and over-attainment and setting the equation eju-i
 goal level. The resulting  problem is  in the form of an  objective function w t
 that can be solved via the  traditional simplex algorithm. However, the goal
 model does not confine the solution to the achievement of the goals. The  '•"
 satisfactory rather than optimum; i.e., the solution  best satisfies the poks u'
 goal attainment.
   Neely  (1973) applied this  technique  to a problem where the  best groUM
 resources projects were to be chosen from a pool of projects. The best projects v
 thai had the highest goal levels. The basis of the Neely  model was defined as
f,(x)=
              NPVjX,
                   J  J
   where,
NPV-
            =  the net piesent value of project j, and
            =  the water resource project (an integer value).

   Transformed into a goal constraint, the objective function becomes:
2  NPVX: -
                        = P
   where,
 P= total dollar value  to be attained by the selected projects.
 This  formulation represents only  one of  several  objective functions employed. Otiu"
 objective functions  were developed  in  a  similar manner to form the complete goa.
 programming structure.  In the  above formulation the X: values indicate which project
 out  of a pool of projects would be  selected. Thus,  the objective function becomes a
 constraint. The problem becomes one of selecting those projects which best satisfy the
-constraint, P (net present value), and all remaining goals.'
   The establishment of policy level (goal  attainment) and/or penalty weights can be i
 significant disadvantage of the goal programming approach. The problem of properly
 valuing  environmental  objectives  thus  also  exists  in  this approach  Environmental
 objectives still must be quantified; in  this case, it is in terms of policy levels. If the Coips
 of Engineers or TVA established the levels  each  would be subject to criticism. However.
 one  possible  solution is the participation  of other groups or individuals in the policy
 decisions.
   Obviously, the goal programming framework provides the advantage of providing a
 means for considering multiple objectives.  But,  a  criterion for any approach will be  its
                                    2-18

-------
I
I
1
I
1
I
I
1
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
  I
  1
  I
  I
                                T'aylor, Davis and North
operationally, i.e.. ease of implementation. One reason for the popularity ot benefit-cost
analysis is its flexibility and lack of complexity. Any alternative  to benefit-cost analysis
will have  to be understandable to  the  parties involved in the decision-making process.
While  goal  programming is  relatively  complex,  the  degree  of  complexity  is  not
prohibitive The technique does offer an approach which  warrants further consideiation
and review.

flic Surrogate Worth Trade Off Method
   The surrogate worth trade off method (Haimes and  Hall, 1974,Haimes er al.,  1975)
is a mathematical programming methodology  similar to goal programming. As in the goal
programming  model,  this  method  provides  a  means  for  considering  a vector  of
.loncommensurable objective futicttions'

   |f,(x). t2(x), .   . frfx))

   In numerous decision  situations the  individual decision maker will evaluate  noncom-
 •iensurable objectives  and determine a best solution.  In  many decisions the individual
 elects between economic and non-economic entities without any common denominator
  \^cpt subjective preference. The decision maker must compare  one or more objectives
 -"- determine which  is of the greatest value. This type of decision-making process is
 ~-x:d on the concepts of Pareto optimality and non-inferior solutions (Ferguson, 1972)
    Hie condition of Pareto optimality exists when an increase in the value of one good in
  "•-' commodity space  can be  achieved  only at the  expense of a  decrease in some other
   M(J A point in the commodity space  is said to be Pareto efficient when any movement
   •' vvould augment the  value of one good reduces the  value of another. This type of
   • Non-making process is transferred to a mathematical programming framework in the
   ''''gate worth trade off method.
    Ijlven a set of objective functions, the decision maker assesses the relative value of the
    '^ °tf of  marginal   increases  and  decreases  between  any  two  objectives.  The
    "Cation procedure requires the determination of when an additional quantity of one
    •--live is worth more or less than that which may be lost from another objective. To
     'mine this trade off between objectives, trade off functions are developed,

         c °'f function between objective functions i and j.
        Ver' when comparing  two objective  functions, they may  be in  noncommen-
     •,.;,  us' For example, fj(x) may be measured in dollars and  f:(x) in acres of land. As
     *  ^e tra(k °ff function would be measured in $/acres. In order to transfer these
     •; .^ ,'*Urable  units  into  commensurate  units,  surrogate  worth functions  are
       -.. ,...   surfogate worth function is a function  of the trade  offs which estimate
       ' • 'i« ^    °ne °bJective over another (i.e., is the marginal change in  one objective
             1 more or less than one unit change in the other objective  function).
                                         2-19

-------
                         Approaches to Multiobjective Planning

   Haimes (1974)  defines a scale from -10 to +10, -10 indicating that ma
f;(x) are worth much less than one marginal unit of f;(x), +10 indicatins rh»   "' ~~
 i                                               Jo LiH; Onrjj
"0" signifying an even trade.                                             rH "•';.
   Once trade off  functions are developed, the  set of feasible solutions  is
considering only non-inferior solutions. If improvement of one objective fun '•'*'•
possible even at the  degradation of another, it is an inferior solution. Howeve  ""  '
an improvement in the value of one objective function for a corresponding degr  .'"*''
the other, it is a non-inferior  solution.  An optimum solution is defined":  t'  c
non-inferior  feasible  solution that  belongs  to the  "indifference  band," a  ? '
non-inferior  solutions where  the improvement of one  objective is equivalent  *
degradation of another. The  optimum is found at the point where all trade   ''•  *
selected to make all surrogate functions equal to "0".                           ' ;';
   The mathematical framework for this approach is not offered here as it is too lo-
an d  complex.  This  presentation  only  reviev/s the theoretical basis  for  the nre'T
However,  Reid and  Vemuri (1971) present an example in their  work  which  sh<-
facilitate a more in-depth understanding of the fundamentals of the technique.
   The major advantage of the surrogate worth trade  off approach is the same as  ih •
goal programming - the  ability to consider multiple objectives. However, in usin^ •<•
surrogate worth trade off method, the decision maker is able to interact with the decisi •
model by assigning subjective preferences to the trade off functions.  This enables ;*•   '
decision  maker to compare the desirability between  two  objectives in  the decisi, •
process.
   However, just as the assignment of goal levels is a limitation in goal programming, $t. t>
the assignment of  surrogates in this method. In fact, the establishhment of surrogates ;^
based almost entirely on  subjective  preferences. This could prove  quite difficult for
public sector agency such  as the TVA or Corps of Engineers. The  determination 01
surrogates for trade  offs seems to  be a more difficult procedure than  specifying poltc,
levels for an objective as required in goal programming. The complexity of this technique
could also prohibit its eventual use.

Other Mathematical Programming Approaches
   Goal programming and the surrogate  worth  trade  off method  are  examples ut
mathematical programming  alternatives to benefit-cost analysis. Other multiple objective
programming possibilities include  iterative programming (Dyer, 1972: Dyer, 1973); the
step method (STEM)  (Benayoun. et al.. 1970; Benayoun, et  al,  1971),  and decision
programming (Hatfield, 1973; Silverman and Hatfield, 1973)  Ritzman (1974) offers an
excellent (brief) overview of all these techniques.

Environmental Evaluation System
   Another  direction that research  has  taken  is to  consider environmental  objectives
separate  from economic  objectives. This  is  achieved by quantifying   the value of
environmental parameters. Two techniques demonstrate alternative methods for assigning
such environmental values.
   The  Environmental  Evaluation System  (EES) is a methodology for conducting
environmental impact analysis of a water resource project (Dee, et al.,  1974). Similar to
some of the math programming models, this approach transforms all parameters into
commensurate  units. However,  unlike other techniques, this  approach considers only
                                    2-20

-------
I
I
I
1
I
 I
 I
 1
 I
  I
  1
  I
   I
   I
   1
   I
   I
   I
   I
1005
                                 Taylor, Davis and North
environmental impact. Developers of this technique feel that since environmental impacts
Cannot  be considered  adequately  within an  economic  framework,  they should  be
considered separately.

   The EES is based on  a hierarchical arrangement of quality indicators; an arrangement
that classifies the  major areas of environmental concern into four major categories:
ecology, environmental pollution, esthetics, and human interest. These four categories are
further  subdivided  into  18 components  and finally 78  parameters.  Each of the  78
environmental parameters represents an aspect of environmental significance worthy of
separate consideration. Each parameter is a physical entity which can be quantified based
on historical data (Dee,ef al, 1974, categorically lists these 78 parameters).

   The parameter estimates are related to environmental quality via a value function. The
value function relates various  levels of parameter estimates  to the  appropriate level of

 environmental quality (where  environmental  quality is measured on a scale from 0, bad
 quality, to 1, good quality). Figure 1  offers an example of this relationship. (Note that
 dissolved oxygen  is  one of 14  parameters in  the  water pollution component of the

 environmental pollution category.)
  environmental
   Quality
                        1.0 r
                        0.8
                        0.6
0.4
                        0.2
                              0
                                     8
10     12
                                                  MG/L

                               Figure 1 . Dissolved Oxygen

     n order to  determine the  relative importance of parameters, each parameter is

   ' f '?nctl a weighted point value. These values indicate the  degree  to which the water
   ./'Urce project may- disturb or  enhance the "dynamic stability of man's relationship to
    - environment". These relative weights are based on the quantification of the subjective
   ' '?nients of the research team performing the  analysis.

         the  above  conditions are met (i.e., value functions are defined and parameters
        hese
          as  to  relative importance), results are combined to  compute  commensurate
            units, referred to as environmental impact units, are computed as follows:
                                            2-21

-------
                          Approaches to Multiobjective Pbnn  <.

   where,
   EIU     = environmental impact units,

   (Vj)w   = value in environmental quality of parameter! with a
   (ViV/o = value in environmental quality of parameter i without
   Pj       = relative weight of parameter i, and
   n       = total number of parameters.
   This  equation measures  the  difference in future  environmental
without the project. The commensurate impact units indicate either a n  ~*' '  *
environmental impact for the  proposed water resource project. These u V
the magnitude of the positive or negative effects of the project.
   Since  this approach considers only environmental objectives, it would h,-
employ  the approach in conjunction with one which considers economic >  b'
may be a more  viable solution than considering all objectives within orm p V
model. The EES offers a means for  quantifying Environmental Impact  Sir-
requirement  of  the  National  Environmental  Policy Act of  1969), hONU.,
decision-making  process some determination  must be  made  to  weigh  cnvu
impact against economic impact. This could pose a serious problem.
   Within the EES model itself, the assignment of weights (via subjective  jua^r
signify the relative  importance of environmental parameters,  may  also be a si-..
limitation. One  research  team's subjective judgements  may  differ substantial,
another's judgments or from an agency's.  It would be necessary to establish a u;,
measure of parameter weights in order to avoid conflicting situations.

Personal Value Evaluation
   This  approach,  as  the  title  indicates,  employs personal  value information jr.,
environmental objectives used  in the water resource  projects (Groves and Kahalas,  14"
It  involves sampling the local population, where a project is to be developed, in orde:
determine  individual  preferences.  Based  on  these  value  judgments,  priorities ..
established for water resource development objectives.
   The  personal value evaluation  is accomplished  via an  interviewing process  wuli
prepared questionnaire. During the interviewing session  the subject is asked to  phw .
scalar value on various environmental parameters.
   This  evaluation process is limited. Like the EES, this method would have to be used u.
conjunction  with  an economic approach.  However,  unlike  the EES,  tliis technique
demonstrates the extreme in subjective judgment estimation. The subjective preference^
are those of the geographically  affected public, which has little scientific or economic
expertise on which  to base or  make judgments. Hopefully, we have not reached  a point
where the public is considered more qualified to make technical judgments than experts
But, the public is qualified to  make their desires known in water resource development.
Therefore, on a limited basis, this technique provides useful information.
   One  additional limitation of this approach concerns the cost and effort required in
conducting  interviews. Many water resource projects are of such magnitude that they can
affect states and regions as well as localities.  As such, the size of the affected population
could make any  type of sampling procedure very expensive
                                     2-22

-------
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
1007                               Taylor, Davis and North


                             CONCLUDING DISCUSSION

   The  four  project  evaluation  approaches   which  have  been   described  offer  an
 indication  of methods  being  developed  to cope with  multiple objectives.  Basically,
 techniques are emerging along two lines. The first, mathematical programming, considers
 all objectives  within a mathematical decision-making model and generates the best or
 most  satisfactory  solution.  The  second, value  determination, quantifies  only environ-
 mental objectives used as inputs to a  decision-making process.
   The authors are of the opinion that no one methodology offers a complete solution to
 the evaluation problem.  It is probable that a complete  solution will not emerge unless a
 combination  of  the approaches  is  employed  However,  of the  four described, goal
 programming surfaces as the most workable It considers all  objectives  within  a  single
 model  framework,  with a minimal degree of complexity. Also, the emphasis on subjective
 judgment  (a factor existing  to a varying degree  in all the techniques) is minimal in goal
 programming.
   It should be recognized that this  review is only a limited examination of each of the
 techniques. However, in each  case  an effort was made  to cite sufficient references. A
 more in-depth look at particular techniques can be found in the respective references.



                                   LITERATURE CITED

 Benayoun,  R., J. Tergny and D. Kevneman, 1970. Mathematical Programming with Multi-Objective
    Functions: A Solution by Progressive Orientation Procedure. Metra, Vol. 9, No. 2, pp. 270-299.
 Benayoun,  R., J. Montgolfier, J. Tergny  and O. Laritchev, 1971. Linear Programming  with Multiple
    Objective Functions: Step Methods. Mathematical Programming, Vol. 1,  1971, pp. 366-375.
 Charnes, A. and W.W, Cooper, 1961. Management Models and  Industrial Applications  of  Linear
    Programming. Vol. I.
 Dee, N,, J.  Baker, N.  Drobny, K. Duke, I. Whitman and D. Fahringer. An  Environmental Evaluation
    System for Water Resources Planning. Water Resources Research, Vol. 9, No. 3, pp. 523-555.
  "Ver, J.S., 1972. Interactive Goal Programming  Management  Science, Vol. 19, No. 1, pp. 62-70.
  kkstein, 0., 1958. Water Resources  Development. Harvard University Press, Cambridge,  Massachu-
    setts.
   «?uson, C.E., 1972. Microeconomic Theory. Richard D. Irwin, Inc., Homewood, Illinois.
   'fives, D. and H. Kahalas. An Empirical Analysis of Personal Value  Information.  Contemporary
    Perspectives in the Decision Sciences (Proc. of 1975 Southeastern AIDS, T.F.  Anthony and A.B.
  -( CanoB,  eds.), pp. 112-113.
  'aimes. Y.Y. and  W.A. Hall,  1974. Multiobjectives in Water  Resources  Systems Analysis:  The
  H Sunogate Worth Trade Off Method. Water Resources Research, pp. 615-623.
   •Jimes, Y.Y., W.A.  Hall and  H.T. Freedman, 1975. Multiobjective Optimization in Water Resource
    Systems. Elsevier Scientific Publ. Co., The Netherlands.
   """""•"I, R.J., 1966. Convention  and Limitation  in Benefit-Cost Analysis.  Natural  Resources
         J.VoL 6, pp. 195-222.
         G-B.,  1973.  The  Theory and  Application  of  Linear Decision  Programming. 8th  Intntl.
   I,, y,mposium on Mathematical Programming, Stanford Univ.
   i.i40 'j' *•• '972. Goal Programming for Decision Analysis.  Aurbach Publ., Inc., Philadelphia.
   *tj '    T-' 1969. Quantitative Analysis of Financial Decisions.  Macmillan Co., New York.
     v°__' J-A., 1959.  The Economic Evaluation of Federal Water Resource Development.  American
            '• Review, Vol. 49, pp. 96-111.
     S
-------
                              Approaches to Multiobjective Planning


Silverman, J. and G.B. Hatfleld, 1973. A Theoretical Approach to Multi.ni..
   20th Intntl. Mtg., Tel Aviv, Israel.                                UHWJbJeciive (.,_ u
U.S. Government, Water Resources Council, 1970. Report ot the Water Reso
   Task Force - Summary of  19  Tests of Proposed Evaluation Procedures"*0" C l'Ulxa>
   Land Resource Projects. Gov't. Printing Office, Washington.              °n Sfle^e>  •
U.S. Government, Water  Resources Council,  1973.  Federal  Register-  Wat
   Resources, Establishment of Principles and  Standards for Planning  Vol ^^  Hr'
   Gov't. Printing Office, Washington.                                '       °'  N° 174
                                           2-24

-------
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 t
 I
 I
i
t
\OL
      NO 5
     WATER RESOURCES BULLETIN
AMERICAN WATER RESOURCES ASSOCIATION
OCTOBER 1973
                   ECONOMIC FORECASTING FOR VIRGINIA'S
                          WATER RESOURCE PROGRAMS'

                       Charles P. Becker, Allender M. Griffin, Jr..
                                   and Carol S. Lo\vn2
   ABSTRACT. Wjter resource and water quality management planning depend, to a large degree,
   on forecasts of industrial activity and population projections. A flexible economic data base is
   especially important where  planning follows varying formats of geographical and industrial
   detail. Records of employment and payroll are  Collected in the administration of Unemploy-
   ment  Insurance (U.I.) programs and are available  trorn State Employment Agencies. These
   -tatistics have been collected over a  long period of record  (thirty-five years)  Many years of
   record are available on punched-cards or magnetic tape jnd mav be arra\c,d and  manipulated by
   Computer  Tins basic approach lias  been lolloped in  Virginia.  Historical L.I payroll and
   employment  records for the period I °-5b through 1970  wore procured on magnetic tape. This
   data  was arrayed by major hydrologic  area and  by regional planning district  Projections ot
   manufacturing activity were  then generated in fitting several exponential  equations to annual
   payroll data  in  two-digit  Standard  industrial Classifications  Ihese exponentials  were then
   extrapolated  to  provide a range of industrial piojcUions  Other parameters ol  manufai. turmg
   activity  were then correlated to the  payroll  data to generate  projections ot indexes such as
   employment, value-added,  and gross manufacturing output. L'.l.  payroll data is  now  being
   Correlated  to parameters in non-manutacturum  categories  Projections  for industries such as
   trade  and services will link extrapolated pavroll data with benchmark correlations ot payroll
   jnd sales receipts.
   iKEY TLRMS- water resource planning, unemplo\ merit insurance (t 1 ) -.tatistiLS, value-added,
   exponential torecastinir. population projections)
  Economic data has  played an  impoitant lolc in watei  resource planning and  water
 -'uhty  management   planning'   Parameieis  such  as  population,  employment  and
 -due-added4  in manut'acuiung  have hoen correlated to  water-use and waste generated

  " Paper No 73066 of the  Water K(.:iourct. J Bulletin  Discussions are open until Vpnl 1. 1974.
    teonwmsts, Virgmra  State \Vater Control  Board, Richmond. Virginia, 232JO
    Between  1966  and   1972,  the  Virginia  Division ot  Water  Resources  ot  the  Department of
 onservation and tconomic  Development was responsible tor comprehensive  water resource planning
  r the State  of  Virginia.  On  July  1, 1972,  the  Division ot  Water Resources was  merged with the
 "gmia State Water Control Board. Since 1946. the  Board has been responsible for  water quality
  •nagement in Virginia. The combined agency is now operating  as the Virginia State Water Control
  jrd.
    'Value-added of  an  industry  consists ot  labor  compensation,  proprietors'  income,  profits,
  '•::est, depreciation, and  indirect business taxes " (U  S. Department of Labor, B L.S . I970i.
                                              2-25

-------
964
                              Becker, Griffin, Jr. and Lown
Water  resource planning engineers and  sanitary engineers are able  to  make Pf <
estimates  of future water-use and  waste levels by  making  correlations with ^
population and industrial projections. Water demand, expressed in millions of ga[j  '••-
day  (MGD)  has  been related  to value-added in selected manufacturing cate-'
Water-use  coefficients  are also available  for other heavy water-using industries su-?*
mining. Domestic water demand can be predicted by applying per capita water-use f-", ""
to population forecasts. Parameters  of water quality such  as biological oxygen den-
(BOD) and chemical oxygen demand (COD) have been correlated to economic index
major  water-using industries. Relationships between per capita population and dom*.
waste generatedjdave also been expressed  quantitatively in terms of BOD  and COD
   In order to produce valid economic forecasts for varying size planning units, the v
resource economist must have a  flexible and comprehensive data base.  Traditional Q'
sources, such as the Bureau of the  Census -  U. S. Department of Commerce, pub; .
data5 which provides a valuable overview  to the  water resource planner.
   Often,  however, more  detailed, unpublished data  is necessary  where planning un,
follow  a  hydrologic  format.  Data  by  reporting establishment  must  be  sorted ^
manipulated to produce a valid benchmark or forecast base for hydrologic planning are
of river basins. Of course, this same data may be sorted by county or  city and i'urthc
aggregated into economic planning regions.
   The State Employment Security  Agencies6  have  collected and stored an impressn
record of payroll  and employment  data  for  administering Unemployment  Insuran,
programs. This  data has been collected in  all of the states, in the territories of Puerto Ri,
and  the Virgin  Islands. Unemployment Insurance (U.I.) laws vary somewhat from state;
state in such areas as program  detail and reporting coverage. Some  states  have, f,
example,  full coverage  in unemployment-insured industries. Other states have require.
U.I.  reports from  firms with four or more employees. Supplementary employment daL
may  be  obtained from  the  Federal  Bureau of Old Age  and  Survivors  Insurant
(B.O.A.S.I.) of the Social  Security Administration to bring coverage  up to a universe c
''100 percent" in these "partial coverage" states.
   The State of Virginia provides a good illustration  where U.I. coverage was partial fo
years (required of firms with  four or more  employees) in unemployment insurei
industries. An amendment (effective  January 1, 1<>72) to the Virginia U.I. law extendeo
coverage  to firms  with one  or more employees  in unemployment insured industries
Certain types of  employers  are  still excluded from U.I.  coverage. Federal  and  loc;,
government,  railroads,  churches  and state  government (except non-teaching staffs 01
hospitals and institutions of higher learning) remain exempt  from U.I. coverage.
   All states, Puerto Rico and the Virgin  Islands submit U.I  employment and payroli
data to the Manpower  Administration under the report designation Employment Securm
(E.S.)  202, The E.S. 202 report is forwarded in the form of a computer print-out. This
record (E.S. 202)  is assembled using individual  establishment reports, i.e., the Employer;
Quarterly  Contribution Report (see facsimile - figure 1). The Contribution Reports are
audited for completeness and accuracy, and then key-punched. Each Contribution Repon
contains the following identification:
    In addition to an every-five year Census of Manufacturers, the U. S. Department of Commerce.
Bureau of the Census also conducts Annual Surveys of Manufacturing during interim years.
    The State Employment  Security Agencies are  affiliated  with the Manpower  Administration
 (formerly the Bureau of Employment Security) of the  V. S. Department of Labor
                                  2-26

-------
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
  1
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 1
 I
 I
 I
 I
 1
I
                            ECONOMIC I ORECASTING FOR VIRGINIA
                                                                                             %5
   I   A four-digit Standard Industrial Classification (S.i.C  ) Code
   2.  A  three-digit  area  code  designating  the  county  or  city  in  winch  the  reporting

      establishment  is physically  located
   5.  A six-digit serial or identification  number unique to each establishment


   A?>  was  mentioned,  U.I   Contribution  Reports are  filed quarterly  and  contain (in

Virginia)  the following data.


   1.  Monthly employment

   2.  Gross Quarterly Payroll
   3.  Gross Quarterly Payroll subject to Unemployment  Insurance

   4.  Quarterly contribution, i  e.. L1 1. tax
   5.  Quarter and year liability (to U 1.) started
   6.  Report date (quarter and year)
                                    VIRGINIA EMPtOYMENT COMMISSION
                                                                          2nd MO
                                                                          3,0 MO
                                                    DATA
                 d HoK«d  but ->ei


                  YES in Whole


                  YES, In Part
                            j  ' TO1A. WAGES tor avor*er  including remunerati
                           3e          -   id ncludi»g oovrr-e-M  over S4 200
S3 COO prior to  January '  '972,


ur.«  January  Ut  VI000  p»o,
                 Dot* of t
                                       CAICUUTIOM QF
                               A, CONTRIBUTION • Mutt-ply totoi o* Line 3 by fox rot*
                                           abov*
                               5 CREDIT MEVOS NO'S ,'
                              I  (Atwoys ottotH wKifa cooy of Cred'* Memo» )
                                per month from du« dot* to do*« O* poymtnl
                               7  TOTAL AMOUNT oue for wh.
                   j DEDUCT


                  rota of 1%
                                   DO NO' want IN fMlS SPACE if f
                I, (or n thit report required >n accofdone* with the Virgifo Unemoloy
                ment Compeniation Act. it tru» and correct and thor no port of the contribution reported wov or is to be, deducted
                                             Signatur« _


                                             T,tl«	
                 BATCH NUMBER

              ORIGINAL . RETURN TO COMMISSION

               VECfC 20(11 101 71) (MOM 10-1 71)
                                 Figure 1. Contribution Report.
                                               2-27

-------
                             Becker, Griffin, Jr. and Lown

                            MANUFACTURING DATA

   Of these items above, employment (item #1) and gross quarterly payroll (nem „,
of particular importance to the water resource planner. Payroll  is of special reie,"'
since when cumulated by  quarter  to an annual figure  it  is a major conipone*",
value-added. This index, value-added, has been and is currently  used extensively ','
economic indicator (past, present and future) of water-use and waste generated Th'V
payroll in manufacturing is also an important component of gross manufacturing o< •-
or value-of-product.
   As  a prerequisite  for access to the E.S. 202 - U.I.  data, it is necessary trn-
requesting agency  be  aware of  the publication restraints and  data non-disclo-
requirements. In Virginia the publication criteria are as follows.

   1. The industry  group must include at least three independent  reporting funvM-
     companies — not establishments).
   2. The industry's employment must be sufficiently dispersed  so that the cotnbi:
     employment of the two largest firms does not exceed 80  per cent of the jrcu-
     total.                                                                        |
   3. Individual firm  data  may not  be published or disclosed  verbally  under „;.   !
     circumstances.                                                               •
   4. E.S.  202 data  may not be  used for law  enforcement purposes, except in •;.  I
     administration of the U.I. law under which the data is required.                   i

   In most states, other detailed economic data  germane  to  water  resource planning <•  '
available in  both published and  unpublished form. In many  instances, the unpublishe:  '
data by firm or reporting establishment is an extremely  flexible planning tool. The dau  :
usually has been collected by reporting unit and contains identification which  is similar t,.
and  compatible with the U.I. reports discussed  above  In Virginia, an Annual Survey >/
Manufacturers is conducted by the State Department of Laboi and Industry  This surve\
is based on a selected sample and represents about 75 per  cent of all manufacturing  •
activity in  the State.  Firms  which participate  in  the survey  :ire assigned the following
identification data:

   1. A four-digit Standard Industrial Classification code
   2. A three-digit county or city code
   3. A five-digit serial or identification number

  The Annual Survey of Manufacturers is conducted by a mailed questionnaire referred
to as the S-l form. Questionnaire data items include:

   1. Total employment
   2. Production worker employment
   3. Salaries and wages (total payroll)
   4. Wages paid to production workers
   5  Net selling value-of-product
   6. Cost of materials
   7. Contract work
                               2-28

-------
  I
  1
  1
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
1
I
                      i,c ONOMK."T ORE CASTING FOR VIRGINIA                 %'


  J.  Phy-ical volume-of-prod'J'jt

  ')  ( apital expenditures

 if)  Anticipated capital expenditures

 I |  ( ost and quantity (KWH) ot electric power consumed


  Value-added  is  not  purveyed directly  as  a questionnaire  item.  It  can  be  easily

uiiipiited, however, as follows


                   Value-added = (Net selling value of products)

                     -  (Cost of materials) - (Contract work)


  The  same publication and  disclosure restrictions as outlined regarding  the E.S  202 -

i  ! data apply to the Annual  Survey of Manufacturing records, (t.e . S-l data).

  In Virginia, extensive  water  resource and water quality  management plans are being

vveloped for the nine major  river basins (see  River Basin Map - figure 2). These studies

v.-re begun by the Virginia Division of Water Resources in 1966 and are being completed

-;  the  Virginia State  Water  Control  Board (see footnote  i)  This  planning  is

wing approached in  a six volume format.7 Within Volume  !1 - Economic Base Study,

.'insiderable emphasis  is placed on  the  analysis of manufacturing data. This priority

•-.•ilects the significance of high  water-use and related high waste  potential of many

.unufacturing categories.

  Much  water resource  planning is  conducted on  a  hydrologic  format.  In order to

 •press benchmark manufacturing data on a hydrologic  basis, a major rearrangement of

i  S  202    U.I. data and S-l  data (Annual Survey of Manufacturing) was necessary. This
      RIVER BASINS IN  VIRGINIA
                       Figure 2.  Major River Basins in Virginia.


   iy .
     '"me I - Introduction; Volume II - Economic Base Study; Volume III - Hydrologic Analysis;
   r'   V   Water Resource  Problems and Requirements; Volume V - Engineering Development
     lv"; Volume VI - Implementation of Development Alternatives.
                                         2-29

-------
                              Becker, Griffin, Jr. and town

realignment of the data went beyond the normal county and city format. The c
city codes were useful, however, as a broad hydrologic sort routine. As a prelimm.'
the punched cards for both the E.S. 202 file and the S-l  file were interpreted an'
by county  and city. Obviously, many counties and  cities are completely within th/
hydrologic areas. In those counties or cities which are situated in two or more hviV
areas, however, detailed address determinations of individual firms had to be mad
necessary, therefore, to have address data for each reporting form or establishment  *
was a specific as possible regarding physical location.  Usually the firm's mailing
coincided closely with  the firm's  physical location. Based  on  this address
hydrologic address  determination could be made. This task was especially easy 
-------
  I
  1
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 1
I
                      ECONOMIC f-ORECASTING FOR VIRGINIA                 969


  K = Asymptote or limit which the trend value approaches as x approaches infinity

  ,  = The distance from the asymptote to the Y-mtercept

  h - The base of the exponential equal to the constant ratio between successive first

      differences of the log Y


  Two other growth trends which are useful as forecasting equations are the Modified

• ^ponential and the Pearl-Reed (logistic). These equations may be categorized  with  the

 , mpertz trend in the broad family of exponential curves. The general equations for  the

"fjr!-Reedand the Modified Exponential may be written as follows:


      Pearl-Reed                              Modified Exponential


    Yc = - - -                 Yc = K + ab x
         I + H) a + bx
  The Pearl-Reed curve  traces a pattern in which  the first differences of the reciprocals
  'he Yc values are declining by a constant percentage. The Modified Exponential curve

  Bribes a trend where the amount of growth declines by a constant percentage.
  hgure 3 provides an illustration of a typical exponential growth  curve. As is evident,

   trend  line  (TT) increases, but  at a  decreasing  rate on  the right of the point  of

   ;:tion. The horizontal line (KK') marks the upper limit of growth or the horizontal
 •  :'iptote.

   \symptotic growth curves approaching horizontal  limits  were  fitted to  the price

   'ted  U.I. payroll  data. Whenever  a  valid  "data fit"  was established, an equation

    'id  An extension of the curve marked a  trend of possible  growth.  Several growth

   •'' luted to various intervals of data in the same historical series were used to create a

   v"  o! projections.  Value-added, gross  manufacturing output  and employment were

    ••"led to payroll data for the forecast reference points.

    Vr to growth curve fitting, it is well  to look  critically  at  several aspects of the data
   '•"** study area:


      ^R appraisal should be made to determine  if historical growth experience  by the

      '-dustry under study is actually a valid trend.
      s 'he available data record of sufficient length  to present a representative trend in

    .  'he "ea and industry under study?
        he historical record of sufficient magnitude to represent a data base wide enough
      ^Portend future industrial development?


      ' experience indicates that price adjusting U.I. Payroll data is an absolute necessity
      growth  curve fitting. Price adjusting,  of  course, eliminates the  fluctuations of
       ^ deflation, leaving "real" changes. Unfortunately,  there  is  no "ideal" price

    '•- iyTCe adJusting payroll or labor costs.
         Resale Price Index9 (published  by the Bureau of Labor Statistics (B.L.S.), U.

      ' * Vk
      ">-rijn!  e P*'06 Index ". . . is an index of the prices at the primary market levels where the
       ^ tul C°mmercial  transaction for each commodity occurs." (Tuttle, 1957). "Wholesale', as
       '; Jist h  thC index' tefers to sales in large quantities, not to prices received by wholesalers,
            lbu
-------
970
                              Becker, Griffin, Jr. and Lown
S. Department of Labor) has proven quite satisfactory when applied to m
payroll data. Most applications have been on the two-digit S.I.C. level using th *!!*'
converted to 1970.                                                       ' "'  .
   The Bureau of Water Resources of the Virginia State Water Control Boa H
available  15 years (1956-1970) of U.I. employment  and payroll data. An itu"
computer is currently being used for the exponential curve fitting routines. Previ  "*
Olivetti Programma  101 (a  programmable calculator) and an IBM 1130 compel
used. The  IBM  360  has, of course,  greatly expedited  curve fitting and extra'-'
routines.                                                                  '  '
   Utilizing the  "360" program, fifteen years  of historical payroll data v/ere fit-
three exponential  curves —  Gompertz, Modified Exponential and Logistic (Pearl k
The  data was analyzed in 6, 9, 12 and  15-year intervals. For fifteen consecutive •,-
data, this method resulted in twenty-two possible curve fits for each two-digit S 1 C •,
there were several different forms which the exponential curves could take, consi-
were built  into the program to eliminate the curves which did not  fit a pattern of n
growth. The desired shape of the growth curve was that which sloped upward to the •
approaching some horizontal limit, while increasing at a decreasing  rate (see figure  "•.,

        400
        390
        300
        250
     O
     o
     £ 200

     O)
     z
     2  iso
     _i
     _i
     i
         100


          50
                    I960     1970     1980     1990    2000    2010    2020
                                        YEARS
                Figure 3. U.I..Pay_roU_estimates and projections in transportation,
                communications and public utilities for the Southeastern Virginia
                   Planning District (data expressed in constant 1970 dollars).
                                           2-32

-------
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
                         ECONOMIC IORKCASTING FOR VIRGINIA
                                                                               07!
   Fifteen years of annual payroll-data (!Q5h-1^70) were read in for each industry  The
first  six-year  period  (1956-1%!)  was anal wed,  and the exponential equation  was
developed. If the  equation  did not violate  the  built-in constraints,  then  the program
extrapolated  tiie historical data from the initial year of the fit period (in this case 1956)
to the year  2020. !f  the equation  violated  the  constraints, a message  was printed out
indicating that  there  was. no tit for  that ^e^es. The second group of consecutive years of
payroll  data  (1957-1962) was then analy/ed This  continued duough  the twenty-two
possible combinations until the final serial ( 1956-1970) had been analyzed.
   The extrapolated  universe  payroll values,  payroll-per-employee, S-l value-added, S-l
gross  manufacturing output  and S-l  payroll were  used in a Programming Language  1
(PL1)  program which generated a table  of protections  for value-added,  gross manu-
facturing output,  payroll and employment  The tables were structured for photographic
reproduction   directly  Irom   the  printout,   thus  eliminating  virtually  all  typing  and
proofing.  The  value-added projections were  developed by computing  die ratio ot S-l
payroll  and  S-l value-added  tor the benchmark  year. This ratio  was applied  to the
extrapolated  payroll  figures  to develop the  universe  value-added projections The  gross
manufacturing output protections were developed in much  ihe same way  The ratio of S-l
payroll  to S-l  gross  manufacturing output was computed for the benchmark year, and
this was applied to the extrapolated payroll values  to  give gross manufacturing output
projections. The extrapolated payroll values  were divided by  the extrapolated payroll-
per-employee figure to develop employment projections for each S.I.C group.
   Because of  the large volume of output  from  the exponentials, another method of
analysis has been devised which expedites the evaluation  of the  extrapolations. A curve
plotting routine has  been added to the  exponential programs so that  each curve  that
extrapolates is  also graphed. This enables the analyst  to pick the best fit from the  plots
without having to analyze reams of computer punt-outs. A FORTRAN IV10 program has
been  written to utilize  the  plotter capability of the IBM 360. This plotter routine will
graph  the  price-adjusted  historical  payroll  data and  all possible extrapolations.  By
employing transparent plotting  paper and a  uniform scaling factor, an  overlay effect is
created for  the  graphic extrapolations  within  each S.I.C. The three  exponentials  -
Gompertz, Pearl-Reed and Modified Exponential  - are thereby grouped and  the trend
selection process is greatly facilitated. A clustering effect is a "reasonable" indication of a
medium range projection.
   A COBOL1' routine is used at  this point  to expand  the extrapolated U.I. payroll to a
universe. This  universe payroll  figure  will include U.I. payroll, B.O.A.S.I, payroll and
non-covered  payroll.  Universe employment  data  can then be estimated by dividing the
universe payroll projections  by extrapolations of payroll-per-employee. Value-added and
gross  manufacturing output (value-of-product) can be projected through correlation of
benchmark payroll to value-added and payroll to gross manufacturing output (G.M.O.).

                            POPULATION STATISTICS

   In Virginia, the Division  of State Planning and Community  Affairs  (D.S.P.C.A.) has

     FORTRAN IV  is a computer language which  is used most  frequently in scientific and
engineering applications. The term FORTRAN relates to the primary use  of the language: FORmula
TRANslating.
    1 COBOL  is  a computer language  which  is used extensively in  business and commerical data
processing. The term COBOL is derived from the expression COmmon Business Oriented Language.
                                       2-33

-------
        Average annual rate of change =  p  _ " I  Xt
                                           W	[
                                            Y   Xl

        e.g.     X[   = 5,629,000 -  1990 State low
                Xj   = 5,198,000 -  1980 State low
                n    =10 (years)
                R    = 0.00799
   A set of ten constants were then computed, live high (Hj) and five low (Lt). These can
 be defined for each ten-year period as the differences between R for the high protection
 (RHj)  and R for the medium (RM[), and the difference between RM[ and for die low
 (RLj):
        LI    = RMi-RL,          i = l,5

   These constants were then applied to each county and city in developing the high and
 low projections.
   RC[  was  computed for  each county  and  city  for  each ten-year  period,  using
 D.S.P.C.A.'s medium projections:
972                          Becker, Griffin, Jr. and Lown
                                                                                   i
been designated as the agency responsible for  the State's population projections. This
Division (D.S.P.C.A.)  has recently published population forecasts for all counties and
cities in Virginia. These projections are on an every ten year basis to the year 2020.
   The planning guidelines of the Virginia Division of Water Resources required a range of
population forecasts. The range of projections (high, medium and low) reflect varying
demographic assumptions. The low projections  assume a very subdued rate of industrial
development  and continued  out-migration of the  resident population. The  medium
forecast is based on a rather vigorous industrial development program. An extremely
accelerated rate  of economic  growth is implicit in  the high projection. High  and low
projections were  generated by fitting the  compound  interest rate formula above and
below  the D.S.P.C.A. forecast (medium). This trend fitting was accomplished  using a
FORTRAN  IV  program  on  an  IBM  1130 computer. County  and  city population
projections developed  by the Virginia  Division of State  Planning and Community Affairs
were used by the Division of Water Resources as the medium range on which the high and
low projections were based.
   The following high and low control totals (in thousands) were assumed for the entire
state:

              1970        1980        1990       2000      2010          2020
High                      5,632      6919       8,500      10,140         12,100
(Medium)       4,648       5,415      6.284       7,222        8,217         9,340
Low                      5,198      5,629       6,100        6,600         7,100

   The average annual rate of change was computed for each ten-year period using the
compound interest rate formula:
                                        2-34

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
                         ECONOMIC FORECASTING FOR VIRGINIA                973
                      Xl

   For a given county or city, then, the high projections were computed as follows:

         Hi (1980) = (1970 Popl'n) (I 0 + /// + RC I) 10
         Hi (1990) = Hi (1980) (1.0 + II2 + RC2) 10, etc.

 and the low:

         Lo (1980) = (1970 Popfn) (1.0 - L / + RC{) ]0
         La (1990) = 1.0(1980)11.0-1^+ RCij 1°. etc.
                           BITUMINOUS COAL MINING

   An analysis of Virginia's bituminous coal mining industry was made in Volume II —
Economic Base Study of the Tennessee and Big Sandy River Basins. Three basic economic
indicators - production, employment and productivity - were presented. Production in
the coal industry is  measured in mine tonnage and has experienced an increasing trend in
Virginia since the late 19th century.  Record keeping has been quite good in this industry
and a comprehensive set of historical data12 is available from the Virginia Department of
Labor and Industry. Based on the availability and continuity of this data, growth curve
fitting and extrapolation was selected as a reasonable forecasting technique.
   Asymptotic growth  curves describe a mineral industry passing through the following
stages:

   1. Period of initial exploration, market development and limited production, a phase
     characterized by slow growth                                             .
   2. Stage of sharply increasing production and  rapid expansion
   3. Period of relative stability where the growth rate levels off with the main emphasis
     on operating efficiency and cost minimization

   The three exponential  curves (Gompertz, Pearl-Reed and Modified Exponential)
discussed on the above  pages were used in this analysis.
   The medium range projection represented the rates of growth believed to be the most
probable. High and low projections were also developed. These three forecasts provided a
range of data wherein certain water resources planning alternatives could be tested.
   Basically  the same approach (asymptotic growth curves) was used to project the future
low  employment trend  in  the  coal industry.  Because  of the historically  declining
employment series, a low range curve with a negative trend  and a lower limit was fitted
and extrapolated.
     Annual Reports, Virginia Department of Labor and Industry, 1951-68.
                                         2-35

-------
                            Becker, Griffin, Jr. and Lown

                              CURRENT PROJECTS

   Recent emphasis in Virginia has been on Metropolitan/Regional Plans to the State's
Water Quality Management Plan. The Metropolitan/Regional Plans are being develop
for Virginia's twenty-two planning districts. Since the planning districts are  aggregations
of entire counties and cities, the data base, described above, was arrayed and  manipuiate/j
using the  three-digit county or city codes. The basic economic parameters developed m
the river basin plans, discussed above, were  also generated for the Metropolitan/Regional
Plans.
   Data is currently being developed for a special water quality management study for the
lower James River Basin. The  project  (The Lower James River Basin  Comprehensive
Management Study), often referred to as the -'3c" Study, was authorized under Section
3(c) of the 1965 Federal Water Pollution Control Act. The purpose of the 3(c) Sludy ,s
to develop a viable water  quality  management plan  for one  of the most intensively
developed sections of Virginia's largest river basin.
   The data being  assembled for the  "3c" Study will include  standard parameters for all
industries and will follow a county and city format Economic data for the "3c" Study is
being generated in terms of a  1970 benchmark  and ten-year projections to the year 2020
Those indexes requiring price  adjustments have been expressed in  constant 1970 dollars
   The  forecasting methodology for the "3c" Study  data will  generally  parallel the
techniques discussed regarding the  manufacturing data. Again, extrapolations of "growth
curves" fitted to price adjusted payroll data will be correlated to other parameters such as
employment and sales. The major exception will be in .1 shift trom the IB.L.S. Wholesale
Price Index to the  B.L.S. Consumer Price Index for price adjusting historical payroll data.
The "3c" Study will place considerable  emphasis on "real" income of the Study area in
relation to the proposed expenditures for water quality management. Payroll data (for all
industries) price adjusted with the  Consumer Price Index should produce  a fairly realistic
indication  of how local  income  can  meet  expenditure  recommendations   Certain
non-payroll data,  however, such  as manufacturing value-added, gros:, manufacturing
output and wholesale trade receipts will be adjusted with the Wholesale Price  Index

                                 CONCLUSIONS

   Economic data adds an important dimension  to water  resource and water quality
management  planning. Payroll and employment statistics  collected to administer State
Unemployment Insurance programs have a multitude of applications m economic analysis
and  forecasting. U.I. data is a continuous, carefully maintained and relatively extensive
set of historical records. It  has been  accumulated  under national guidelines  of the U. S.
Department of Labor, Manpower  Administration and is  quite uniform  in  format. U.I.
records have,  for  years,  been structured  for  data  processing  applications. Further
manipulation of this data such as price adjusting and  trend fitting are  thus facilitated.
Most  of  the  standard economic  parameters of  water  resource  and  water  quality
management  planning  such as  value-added and gross  manufacturing output have  been
correlated  to  U.I.  payroll  and  employment  benchmarks.  The  Annual  Survey  of
Manufacturing (Virginia Department of Labor and  Industry) piovides value-added and
gross manufacturing output data. County and  city detail and a data processing format is
an  important feature of the Annual Survey (S-l). Both the U.I. and S-l  data have  been
further  formated by hydrologic area in Virginia. On balance,  the U.I. and S-l data  have
                                  2-36

-------
     I
     I
    I
    I
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
                        ECONOMIC FORECASTING FOR VIRGINIA                  975


become valuable tools for water'resource and water quality management  planning  in

Virginia.



                                 LITERATURE: CITED


 Tuttlo, Alva \l. 1957. Elementary Business and  Economic Statistics. New York, N. Y.  McGraw-Hill
   Book Company, Inc.
 U. S. Department of  Labor,  Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1971. Handbook of Labor Statistics, Bulletin
   1705. Washington, D.C.
 U. S.  Department of Labor,  Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1970. Patterns of U. S. Economic Growth.
   Bulletin 1672. Washington, D  C.
 Virginia Department of Labor and Indu>try. 1951-68. Annual Reports. Richmond. Virginia.
                                        2-37

-------
              ECONOMIC  VALUATION  OF SHORELINE
                   Gardner M. Brown, Jr. and Henry O. Pollakowski*
               I..  Introduction

O HORELINE  development  is  a  growing
^J public  policy issue  in  many urban areas.
While there is some  published research on  a
related  topic, the importance of ambient water
quality, economists have  not yet turned their
attention  to the  economic significance  of  the
existence  and width of the undeveloped apron
offering public  use  and  access to bodies  of
water   in   urban  areas.   There  are  several
important issues  to be considered here. May we
expect  the urban  land market  to  provide  a
solution which is Pareto efficient? Have public
agencies  through  zoning   and  other  building
restrictions acted  in  a  socially  optimal way''
What  contribution  can  studies of  the  de-
terminants  of property  values  make  to  our
understanding of  these issues?  We  begin an
exploration of these  issues and  present some
empirical  results that enhance our  knowledge
of the economics of water-related open space.
  More generally,  this paper extends  recent
economic work that has produced quantitative
measures   of  value  for  phenomena  hitherto
restricted  to qualitative expression The process
of transforming  qualitative  into quantitative
knowledge, so essential to an empirical science
as to be  one of Us  distinguishing features,  is
well   illustrated  b\  the   work  of  C'ubb  and
Douglas on production (1928).  Gnhches (I%I)
on  the  qualitative characteristics of  automo-
biles,   and   Fogel   and   I-ngerman's  (1974)

  Received  for  publication December 1. IV"?  Revision
accepted  for publication Septembei 11  I97ti
  •Richard  Parks.  Richard  Haitman  l.evis  Kochm,
Ronald T rosper, Cindy Watts, and in anonymous reieree
provided  helpful criticism of earlier versions ol this paper
Ron Johnson, our research assistant, deserves credit lor
many valuable suggestions, including the germ of the idea
in the final section  The \vork  upon which ihis  paper is
based  was  supported in  part by  funds provided by  ihe
United States Department of the Interior. Office of Water
Resources  Research as  authorized  under  the Water
Resources Research Act  of 1964  through  the State  of
Washington  Water Research Center  Henry  Pollakowski
also acknowledges partial  support by National Institutes
of Health research grant number I ROI HD07410-02 from
the  National Institute of Child  Health  and  Human
Development, Center for Population Research
[272]
controversial piece on slavery.1 Wiih respect to
housing,  implicit   prices  of  each  attribute
contained  in  the bundle of  housing  services
have  been estimated   by  hedonic  price re-
gressions in the spirit of the work by Lancaster
(1971) and others.2
  In the following sections we first examine the
choice of  housing attributes,  including water-
related open space and proximity  to bodies of
water, faced by a household in a metropolitan
area.   Next,  the  process  of  implicit   price
formation  is examined, and, employing data on
individual  dwelling units in a metropolitan area
with numerous bodies of water, these implicit
prices  are  estimated.  We  then   turn  to the
question of what can  and cannot be  inferred
from  these  results about the demand for  open
space and  the welfare  gains or losses resulting
from   possible  changes  in  the  amount  of
water-related  open space.
         II.   Implicit Price Estimation

   -\ given housing unit is best characterized as
consisting of  a  bundle  of  attubutes  which
describe  the  structure itself,  the  land upon
which it  is huili.  and  the  relevant locational
characteristics.  We   thus  view  pioMinity  to
water and water-related  open  space (i.e.  the
land  contiguous to water to  which  the  public
has access and  which we  define as setback) as
  ' Rt-'se.nch ihai Uerues the  .mplicit  -.alue ot  natural
environmental  .uuinuies or activitiei  that  use  natural
environment intensively includes tiic work by Hammack
and Brown on waterfowl ( I'"1"-}) cattle bingn and Brown
(1964) and Mathers and Brown (l^"0f  on ".ports salmon
fishing, and DLIMS I l%4) and Krulilla and Fisher (1975)
on wilderness  Ihe Krutilla and  Hshei reference  both
refers  to and summarizes interesting related research bv
Cicchetti and V  k Smith
  'Contributions employing micro data and specifying ;he
bundle of housing services  in an  interesting manner
include Kam anil" Quigley (197Q). King (1973),  Polla-
kowski (1973, 1977). and Grether and MiesAowski (I9"4)
The natural environmental attribute so  studied has  been
ambient  air quaht\  See Freeman (1974).  P^lmsky and
Shavell (1975. 19"6)  and Srna!l (19,'5)  for discussion of
the theoretical issues involved in interpreting  the results o!
the air quality studies and for further references
                                         2-38

-------
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
                       ECONOMIC VALUATION OF SHORELINE
two locational attributes of the housing bundle.
At  any  given  tune,  there  exists   a   given
distribution over space of the supplies of these
attributes  \Ve make this assumption since  the
housing stock  is altered only slowly  over time.
and because  some  attributes, such  as certain
neighborhood  amenities,  are supplied perfectly
tnelastically.
  On  the  demand  side,  assuming  a   given
spatial distribution of employment and a given
distribution  of preferences and  income over
households,  we  ma>  envision  a distribution
over space of demands for these attributes The
housing market is thus viewed as consisting of
implicit  markets for each  of the attributes of
housing,  broadly  defined,  and  it is assumed
that at  any  given point in time a vector of
implicit  short-run equilibrium prices  exists.
  For  the   sample  areas,  estimates  of  the
marginal implicit prices of each of the dwelling
unit  attributes were obtained  by  regressing
dwelling  unit  selling price  on  the  set  of
variables representing  the  attributes that con-
stitute  the  relevant  housing  package.  The
choice of functional  form to be  employed was
based  upon a number of considerations.  There
are, of  course,  a  large  variety of  possible
nonlmeanties and interactions among housing
attributes one may  wish to consider.  Limited
experimentation,  however,  with   functional
forms  other  than linear ones did not substan-
twely alter our basic results. We  thus chose to
present results of the linear form,  while altering
any right-hand variables whenever there was an
* priori reason  to  believe  that  an  important
nonlineanty existed.3
  The- sample areas  or  Neighborhoods  are
iocated  in  Seattle:  this  city is   ideal  for our
purpose since it contains numerous and  varied
bodies of water, some of which are surrounded
by  open space and some  of which are not.
Numerous potential sample areas located close
'o bodies of water were considered for use. The
"lost  important objective  was   to  achieve a
relatively high degree of homogeneity  within
an-d across  areas. Neighborhoods chosen were
S'rnilar   m   topography,   non-water-related
neighborhood  characteristics, and accessibility.

  3See  Grether  and  Mieszkowski  (1974) for   further
discussion  of  choice  of functional  form and for a
comparison of results ortin^ar and semilegamlunic forms..
 •\reas that contained or were adjacent to large
commercial zones  were eliminated from con-
sideration, and only  those  areas adjacent to
bodies of vvuter used extensively for recreation
purposes   were  employed.  The  number  of
feasible  choices of  areas with  setback  was
severely  limited by  lack  ot  variation  in the
width  of  the  setback  area  m numerous  areas.
Finally,  a  number  of otherwise  acceptable
areas were eliminated due to physical obstruc-
tions such  as  railroad tracks  that  inhibited
ready  access  to the waters  edge  or setback
area.
   This selection p'ocedure yielded  three  areas
--one exhibiting  significant  variation  in set-
back width and two with  no setback Each of
these  ,yreas  is  an  almost exclusively  single-
family residential area, and since each  area is
within the Seattle city limits nominal property
tax rates do not vary One of the areas without
setback is located on Lake Washington, a very
large inland body of water. I he remaining two
areas encircle  two smaller lakes. Green  Lake
(vvith  setback)  and   Mailer   Lake  (without
setback).  The boundaries  ot the sample  areas
were based, in part, on  pievious work by others
which indicates that the contribution of a water
resource  to  property  values  generally  is not
significant beyond 4.000  feet from  the water's
edge.4 In one  area (Green  Lake). 4.000 feet was
used. In the other areas. 2.200 feet was selected
because  our  criteria  for  homogeneity  would
have been violated had a greater distance been
included.  For example, in one area a change in
topography at  a  distance of   3.000  feet  was
accompanied  by  a  sharp  change  in  racial
composition of the dwellers.
  The data employed  consist  of market  sales
data  for  dwelling units   in these  areas sold
during the period  1969-1974.  The data  were
obtained  from  listings of  sales  data  gathered
from real  estate sources.5 For each observation,
this  data  source includes  selling price  and a
rather rich description of the  structural  attri-
butes.  The selling price data were deflated to
constant 1967  dollars by use of a price  index
  "See- for example, Dornbusch and Barrager (1972).
  5 Sales data, incjuding selling price and corresponding
structural characteristics, were obtained from the monthly
publications of the SREA Market Data Center Inc., April
1969 to June 1974.
                                                   2-39

-------
274
THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
for Seattle single family dwellings.6  The open
space  variable  employed was constructed  by
measuring the width  of  setback area abutting
the water and .closest to. the dwelling unit in~
question. Setback  appears in log form in the
regression because we had  a strong reason to
believe that the relationship between setback
and selling price was  a nonlinear one. That is,
we  believed  that  as  setback  width  was
increased, marginal  contribution  to  housing
value would decrease. We thus assume that the
marginal implicit price of setback vanes with
the quantity of  this attribute purchased. The
distance  to  waterfront was  measured  as  the
shortest  linear distance from  the dwelling unit
to the  nearby waterfront. It, too,  appears in the
regression in log form because we believe the
relationship between distance to waterfront and
housing value is essentially nonlinear.
   The regression results are presented in  tables
1 and  2,  It should  be noted  that not all of the
structural  information  on the individual dwell-
ing  units  is employed.7  A  number  of  these
structural  variables, such as  a  set of dummy
variables  representing  different  heating fuels
used, made essentially  no explanatory contribu-
tion in earlier regressions and are thus deleted
in the results  presented here. Since tests on
preliminary  regression  runs   indicated   the
presence of heteroscedasticity. all observations
are weighted by  I/living area
  Table  1  presents  results foi our setback area
(Green Lake), one of the more interesting areas
and the  one with the largest sample  size. The
lake itself has  a circumference  of about three
miles  and is completely  surrounded  by  green
area   with   public  access.   The green   area
surrounding  the lake is very popular  for public
use, including  a  cycling/jogging  track  and
swimming,  fishing,  and  boating facilities. As
mentioned  above,  the  width  of the  setback
vanes  a  good  deal  as one  moves  around  the
lake, making this an especially appropriate area
to study. In table  2 we present results  for  a

  6A local price index for single  family residential sales
within the Seattle metropolitan area was used as a deflator
The source was Seattle Real Estate Research Committee
(Fall 1974)
  'Although available, we did not employ the following
structural characteristics' number of rooms above the first
floor; the  number of bedrooms, the existence of a"den.
family room, or recreation  room: special improvements.
type of  garage; and type of heating fuel  used
                            pooled  sample consisting  of the  two  areas
                            without setback, in both cases nearly all of the
                            coefficient estimates  are  of  the  hypothesized
                            signs  and . the   explanatory  power  of  the
                            right-hand variables is quite high.
                              The results bearing on  the  value of distance
                            to waterfront and size of  open space are quite
                            interesting. Applying the appropriate one-iaiiej
                            /-tests, in each case we can reject at the 001
                            level  the  null hypothesis  that  the  coefficient
                            estimate of the distance to waterfront variable
                            is zero. In the setback  case (table  1),  \ve can
                            reject at the 0.051 level the null hypothesis that
                            the  setback coefficient estimate is zero. Havine
                            corroborated   our  presumption  that   these
                            variables  would  be statistically important,  the
                            implications  of the actual magnitudes of these
                            two coefficient estimates are  now examined
                              Consider first  the  effects  of  setback  itself.
                            Recall  that   we  are  assuming   that the  re-
                            lationship  between setback size and  dwelling
                            unit value is  nonlinear: that  the  benefits of &
                            green area along the  waterfront  to which  the
                            public has access  are captured in land values in
                            the  proximity  of  the  body of water: and that
                            the   existence  and  width  of  setback  in  the
                                  TABLE 1 —RHSLLTS FOR GREIN LAKF. \REA
                                  Left-hand Variable: Selling Price (deflated to
                                              1967 dollars)
                                  All observations weighted by 1,  living area
                                                 ,V = M
Variable
Constant term
Living area (sq. ft.)
Age of house
Average room Mze
Number of fireplaces
Number of car garage
Number of rooms 1st storv
Number of bathrooms
D = \ if basement
D = 1 if dishwasher
D = 1 if good or excellent
quality
D = 1 if range and oven
D= \ if hot water heating
D= 1 if wall or floor
furnace heating
D= I if electric heating
Lot size(sq ft.)
D = \ if view
Log of distance to
waterfront
Log of individual setback
size
SSR=197
Coefficient
15700
338
-733
-5 51
1120
074
-311
2830
1260
2010

289
255
1040

-2200
- 1660
- 0 247
573

- 1770

1230
S E. = 1 66
Standard Error
3400
1 17
154
725
415
455
265
007
464
784

486
"MS
1 140

801
903
0.195
693

762

744
R-= 84
                             Source*,  of Data  Selling price  and structural  characteristic
                            SRt-A Market Dala Center  Ine  (\pr:l ! l>69 to  June H'-t)
                            Dislanc-e u> waterfront and setback si/e mea-mcd on  local maps
                                         2-40

-------
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
                        ECONOMIC VALUATION  OF SHORELINE
                                          275
   T\BIC 2.—Rf.SL'LTS FOR ARfcAS WITHOUT SETBACK
     Left-hand Variable: Selling Price (deflated to
                  1967 dollars)
      All observations \veiehted bv 1 / living area
Variable
Constant term
Living area (sq ft )
Age of house
Average room size
Number of fireplaces
Number of car garage
Number of rooms 1st story
Number of bathrooms
D= 1 if basement
0= 1 if dishwasher
0= 1 if good or excellent
quality
D= 1 if range and oven
£>= 1 if hot water healing
D= 1 if wall or floor
furnace healing
0= 1 if electric heating
Lot size (sq. ft )
D=l if view
D=l if in Haller Lake
area
Log of distance to
waterfront
SSR = 380
Coefficient
16500
4.17
-74.6
- 138
417
1510
-444
5120
300
308

289
298
57QQ

-540
-2250
0.235
1340

-1730

-2790
S.E. = 2.33
Standard Error
3580
1 84
40.0
11 6
608
617
399
1190
831
888

649
839
3380

998
1110
0 104
1110

706

548
«'= 78
sample  affects  all dwelling  units  which are
proximate to  the  body of  water  equally. The
effect of variation  in setback in the Green Lake
-area  is  quite  substantial.  A  dwelling unit
located  in  an area  close  to  a  200  foot wide
setback will sell for about $850  more  than a
comparable  one located near a  100 foot wide
setback  area.  This  same  dwelling unit,   if
located  near  a  300  foot  wide  setback  area.
would sell for  about $1,350 more than if it were
located near a 100 foot setback  area.
  The estimates of premiums paid for proxim-
ity to shoreline are "very plausible ones  for the
Seattle area,  and, as we would  expect,  this
premium declines  with distance to waterfront
much more  rapidly  in the  case of  no setback
than  in  the  setback  case.  Applying  the
appropriate  F-test, we can  reject at the 0.05
ievel the  null  hypothesis that  the  respective
coefficient  estimates of  the  distance  to wa-
terfront variable are equal.  In  the  case of  no
setback, we observe that  three-fourths  of the
location value of proximity  to water has been
lost  at  a   distance  of  300  feet  from  the
waterfront.

          III.  Optimal Open Space
  The next question to be  examined is whether
the  amount of  open space  around the water
bodies studied is optimal. A necessary first step
is  to decide  in what manner  our estimated
hedonic  price equation can be used to answer
this question.
  First,  consider the  measurement of benefits
of open  space. Gi\en  that willingness to pay is
the appropriate measure of the \alue of open
space, we wish to obtain an estimate of the area
under the demand function for open space The
estimated hedonic price function itself  is most
appropriately  viewed  as  an opportunity  locus
facing  households  in  the housing   market.8
Taking   the derivative of  this  function  with
respect   to setback  gives  a marginal  implicit
price function. This  function,  which  will be
downward-sloping  and convex  from  below  in
the  case of  setback, is  most  appropriately
viewed as the locus  of the marginal willingness
to pay functions of households.
  Assume that the characteristics embedded in
housing  are not obtainable by  the purchase of
other products, and that  utility  functions  are
weakly   separable   between   housing  service
characteristics and other chaiactenstics.  If we
then  assume  that migration among metropoli-
tan  areas  is  possible,  that  households  have
equal  incomes,  and  that households  have
identical  utility  functions, it  follows  that all
households  will  have identical  marginal  will-
ingness   to  pay  functions.0 In  this  case,  the
estimated marginal implicit price function may
be   appropriately  viewed  as  the  marginal
willingness to pay function, and an estimate of
the value of open space may be obtained from
the  function  we  have  estimated. Given  the
nature of the assumptions necessary  to  make
this  calculation, there is good  reason  to regard
the results obtained as indicating only rough
orders of magnitude.10'"
  8See  Freeman  (1974) and  Rosen (1974) for  a  more
detailed discussion of these matters.
  'Polmsky  and  Shavell  (1976).  assuming  identical
Cobb-Douglas  utility functions and  equal  incomes,
identify the demand function  for air quality in a general
equilibrium model.
  10If we wished  to consider only very  small changes in
open  space, it would not be necessary to assume identical
preferences. While separability between open space and all
other characteristics must be assumed in this case, it may
not be  unduly restrictive given the degree of change
envisioned. See Small (1975) on this matter. We  must
further  assume a zero income elasticity demand for
setback  in order  to make the estimated demand  curve
correspond to a compensated demand curve. The  latter
                                            2-41

-------
276
          THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATIST ICS
  The determination of optimal open space is
straightforward. If those  \vho benefit from the
water-related open space  are also the owners or
renters of property, then the added value for all -
property  affected by  slightly  changing  the
amount  of  open  space  should just  offset the
cost of buying the property or the added space.
Since a  land value gradient can be  computed
from the estimated hedomc price equation,  we
have enough information to  perform  a rough
calculation.12
  On the assumption that the  boundary of a
water body is well described by  a circle with
radius r, and that all properties have the same
area A, the  number of properties within a band
of land  of  width  Q  from  the water's  edge  is
given by
The marginal number of properties at Q is
Optimal open  space is  found  by  maximizing
with respect to open space, Qs.

         Q
     = \   \  (O)V(Q.O
       J
        Q,
         1
'<2s.\"(0)l
where  ('((2-0,) is the value of a property whose
distance to the water is Q. and where (5, is the
width  of_ the  strip of open  space around the
water.  Q is  the distance from the  shoreline
beyond which it is assumed  that properties  no
longer  benefit from this open space
  The  first expression on  the right-hand side of
(1)  represents the benefits of  setback or  open
space,   embodying  the   assumption  that  all
provides a conceptually  preferable basis for estimating
willinuness to pay
  11 XVhen assumptions stated in the text cannot be made.
Freeman  (1974)  proposes a  pragmatic  -olulion  for
estimating the  value of  environmental  change  SimpU
compute the marginal benefit for ea^h individual usung the
hedomc price equation, tmd the mean value and assume
the  demand curve is linear This "demand" curve will cut
through the marginal hedomc price equation revealing that
people on the lower end of the ad hoc "demand" curve are
willing to oay less than actually has been  observed  We
point out this limitation without prejudging the practicality
of the suggestion
  12 There may  be added cost of restoring  the purchased
land to "open space" qual'tv if it was formerly developed.
but  this is an analytically  inessential point
                                     property located between  the edge of the on->
                                     space  and  Q benefits from  open  space  T^
                                     second expression on  the right-hand side of (\\
                                     -represents the opportunity  cost of open sp^,'
                                     the  foregone private  value of  each propel,
                                     which could have  been  located between  -i'.''
                                     water's edge and  the  terminus of  the on^
                                     space. Anticipating the next stage,  we  den-"^
                                     the inverse demand function for open space C
                                     h(Qs) and note that u  is simply dl'(Q.O )/,)Q
                                        Figure  1  illustrates the nature of the probl^Ti
                                     In the absence of any setback or public acce-
                                     the value of all property at the  lake shore nrri
                                     equals  N0V0. The  value  of  property decline'^
                                     with distance until a distance of Q is reached
                                     When  setback  equals  £>.,• the  value  of   (»
                                     property  at  that distance  from water is higher
                                     than  it would  have  been in the  absence  of
                                     setback. The optimal  setback  occurs when  the
                                     loss  of private  property value near the shore
                                     (2o-^o' o-^Q;- 1S compensated  by  the gain  to
                                     remaining  properties.  ABCE. from  additional
                                     setback.
                                        The necessary condition for a maximum b

                                        lQ*'(Q)h(Q,)dQ- [Q'*'(Q)ti(Q>)dO
                                        •'Q,                   Jo
                                      Revising, after noting that h(0.) is independent
                                      of O. yields
                                                                Q'
                                                                  \
                                        A comparison  between  actual  and optimal
                                     open space is made by  drawing on  the results
                                     for Green  Lake, and by  assuming  that the area
                                     under   the  marginal  implicit  price  function
                                     accurately  reflects willingness to pay  Optimal
                                     open space is about  !00 feet compared to the
                                     actual  average distance of about  3'X) feet  \t
                                     100  feet the net benefit  ot  open space is about
                                     $13  million,  falling  about  one  half  million
                                     dollars  when the amount of setback  is 200 feet.
                                     on average  Computed  nei  benefits fall  b\
                                     somewhat  more  than SI  million  (about  10^)
                                     when the radius of open space  is  increased ;o
                                     present levels  Of  course,  many people in the
                                     greater  Seattle  area benefit from the use of the
                                     open space around Green Lake but do not I'M
                                     within the  4.000  feet perimeter  specified in '.he
                                    2-42

-------
    I
    I
    I
    I
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
                        ECONOMIC  VALUATION OF SHORELINE
             E^ $r\i_E. DI?T\SCE re
              \SD PROPER!"1! \ \LLE
                                                                                v.r.e xol
 ;ample. \V'e have thus provided a lower bound
 'o the measurement  of  total and  marginal
 jenefus of open space, and this must be borne
 .n mind  in interpreting the above calculations.
 ^e  cannot conclude confidently  that optimal
 open space is lower than actual. Note also that
 the  net benefit function is fairly flat.  Under-
 sstimaied marginal benefits amounting to less
 '-an a capitalized \alue  of  $100  per  house
 *ould shift the optimal \vidth of open space to
 ^OOfeet.13
     IV.   Open Space: A Public Decision
  U is" appropriate to consider open space as a
public  good  as  long  as  partial  rivalry  in
consumption (congestion) is not an  important
consideration.  While  an  existing  owner  of
property  can  capture  through  exchange  a
Portion of the value  of  open space, should it
aPpreciate — this  was  the motivating assump-
ton of  our empirical investigation — owners of
property  cannot individually  determine  the
°Ptirnum  open space. Some form of collective
action is  called for. Alternatively, the  right to
°eterrnine the  open  space  could be granted,
w'th  or  without compensation, to  an om-
niscieru   entrepreneur,  admonishing   him  to

   The number of homes benefiting is about 6,300. The
dlscussion is in terms of 100 foot increments to conform
*llh customary lot dimensions.
• \rERFRosr      benav e  >.'•  .1
               competitive  _-.,-! :>;; .>"   Bu
               unconventional ,.xpec' to
               which  makes the  reguiau
               cumbersome one
                 Our empirical  rexul'.x indicate
               of  a  property  taPs  wth  d'.xta
               water '4   Theretore.   the   n\.r^i:'..u  vox;  or
               pro-peity exchanged in a competitive "i.nket is
               falling as we move avv^v f'om  t'ne wv.;er  Since
               the average cost  is gre.iter than  marci'ial cos;
               an entrepreneur seeking  at', optima! amount of
               open space cannot cover h'x coxtx it v vi'.-.vx
               tne ci mpe'nt'.ve  prescription ot  xett''!c   p-^e
               ecjual to  marginal ».ost  of  open space  \\  ill
               benef.cianes  Eu'nei  the  enuepreneu:  ;'i'.:s'  ne
               permitted to deviate from marginal co>> piling
               or he must receive a subsidy  T"ne  othei  ni.iioi.
               solution  is for the public sector  to  '.ike  direct
               responsibiliu  [or piovid'ng optima', open  space
               Falling cost p!u>  itubilir, to exclude are two
               traditional  economic  tea.xons   why  trie  de-
               termination of open space around water bodies
               is likely to remain vety much a  public issue and
               will be resolved by  the public sector
                 Of  course,  with falling  marginal  costs  of
               acquiring open space, a  tuul calculation  must
               be  made to insure that  the  total  benctits  of
               open space are greater than  the total costs This
               condition holds for our representative  area

                                REFERENCES
               Castle. E  N .  A Singh, and  \V  Broun,  -tn  Economic
                    Evaluation  of the  Oreyn Salmon  and  Siet'lhead
                    Sport Fishery. Technical Bulletin No  7$ (Corvalhs.
                    Oregon State  University  Agricultural Experiment
                    Station. 1964)
               Cobb.  C.  W,  and   P.   H.  Douglas. "A Theory  of
                    Production," American  Economic Rene* 18 (Mar
                    1928), 139-165
               Davis.  R.  K... "The Value of Big Game Hunting in a
                    Private Forest." Transactions of the Twenty-Ninth
                    North American Wildlife and Natural Resources
                    Conference (Washington. D.C.: Wildlife Manage-
                    ment Institute,  1964^393-403.
               Dornbusch, D. M., and S. M. Barrager. Benefit of Water
                    Pollution Control on Property Values  (Washington,
                    D.C..  U.S. Environmental  Protection  Agency,
                    1972).
               Fogel, R. W,. and S. L. Engerman, Time on the Cross. The
                    Economics  of American Negro  Slavery (Boston:
                    Little Brown] 1974).

                 l4This result also makes analytical sense in the setback
               case if the open  space yields an  unambiguous flow of
               favorable  services. But it might not  Open  space can
               attract group-? of people  who are noisy, thus creating a
               disamenity.
                                            2-43

-------
THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS
Freeman. A. M., "On Estimating Air Fo:iut.on Cc.n:rcl
      Benefits  from  Land Vaiue  Studies," J^.-:-l :j
      EKzironn-.cn:jl E cc;;jr::cs t^r.J  M^::j^n:^::t \ (May
      19'4). 74-S3.                     "
Grether,  D. M.. and  P.  Miesr-kowski. "Deisnrur.ar.ts of
      Real  Estate Values." J^rr.jl of f,~j:i Ecci-.^n.cs 1
      (Apr. 1974). 127-146.        '
Gnhches Z.. "Hedonlc Price Indexes of \utcrnobslis-  \n
      Econometric- A«at>f!S of  Quuliu  Chiage." The
      Pr:ce Statistics of ;he Federal Goverr.r.-.ent. General
      Series No  73  (Ne-.v York  National Bureau  of
      Economic Researcn, I9ol).
Hamnuck.  J.  M.  and  G. M   Bro*n.  lij^-rton/  j.iJ
      Ht'/.'jnJs:  fjKu.'J  B.o-<.cc;Kjm.c A/:^i\s:s  tBaiti-
      more: Johns Hopkins Pre^s, 1974).
Ram, J.  K... and J  M. Qmgiey. "Measuring the Value of
      Housing  Quality."  Jturr.ji of the American Suusii-
      cj/ issxunot 65 (June  19"0).  532-548.
King. \. T.. Prjptn\  Ta\es,  Air.smi.es. arj Rts:Jtr.t.jl
      LJI^ I j."«« (CambnJce-  Balhnger Publishing Co .
      19":-1                "                     "
krutiila.  J. V .. and  \.  C  Fixr.er. The Ecor.jm,is cf NJJM/-J/
      Eni.rsnmtius. Sl-J:cf in  ire I j/'uj;;. •? t-t" C^.nm^j.iv
      ^"J  Imcni:; Res^«rccs (Baltimore: Jonr.s Hopkins
      Press, l^'f")
Lancaster.  K.  .1 . dwurxr Derr^r.^  ^  \o»  ArrrJ~c'<
      i\eu York  Co':urnr Preis.  i9"i)
Mathews. S  B . and G M Bro«n. Ecc-r. T.IC Em;^:.^-. ji
      .r.j j'°o? S.v."/ S-.--.~i r.j ;.\.
      Technical  Report No. I  i._C;>
      DipartmeatcfFiihen.es. 19.0).          "
Polmsky, A. M.. and S. Shavell. "The AST Poihi.
      Property  Value  Debate,"  this  REMENV  ^
      19'5). IGo-1 10.
- ,  "Arnsnif.es and Property Valass ;n a Mod-.
      L rban  Area."  A-,.-..:;  sf  P.b! c  £- ~-*
      (Jin.-Feo. 1976X ! 19- !29. "           "   '
Pollako^ski, H. O . "Thr Hf«cts of  Loci!  Pabl.c S;
      en Residential Location Decisions   An Err--
      Siudv for  the  San  Francisco Eia\  Area '  -
      lished Ph.D. dissertation,  L'ni\srii;\ of  Ca> ••-
      Berkeiev. 1973.                          " ^
- ,   "Local  Public  Services,  Rental \aii.e<
      Residential  Choice."  University of  V,a:r",n
      1977. mimeo.
Rosen, S., "Hedomc  Pr.ces and Implicit Markets  Pr
      Dilfercnuauca in Pure Competition."  Jour^
      Pjimtjl Ecor.3m\ S2 (Jan  ;Feb  1974). 34-^'
Seattle  Real   Bute   Research Committee. R^i
      Res?-r;fi  Ripen  fjr   ,r.£  C.n o'  S=j.v/-
      \ijtrcp^!it^t And (SeAll.i. F^ll \^~4)
Smaii. K A., "Air Pollut.on and Property \iiues  F-
      Ccmroer.t," this REMEW 57 (Feb. 1975i  i\j_|
SREA Market Dau Center Ir.c .  Sir^'f rjir..!,  Rn^t
      Sj:es (.Seattle.  April 19&9 to June 19"4>
                                                                                l'4
                   2-44

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
Economics

L. D. JAMES, School of Civil Engineering,
Georgia  Institute  of Technology, Atlanta,
Ga.

 A major  event  involving  the economics
of water pollution control during 1975 was
the release of the draft report of the Na-
tional   Commission  on  Water  Quality
(NCWQ).1  In a summary  of the report,
Ward 2  noted  the projections  of  down-
ward trends  in industrial water  use and
pollution control  costs and generally small
price  impacts  resulting  from   national
water  quality  standards.   Dallaire 3 de-
scribed how federal  grants for  construc-
tion  of  municipal water  quality  control
measures are bogged down in the red tape
of project evaluation; he discussed findings
of NCWQ and EPA that  place the cost  of
meeting  1983 municipal  water  treatment
goals as high as $342 bil:  $28 bil for waste
treatment,- $79 bil for sewers, and $235 bil
for stormwater treatment and control.  The
U. S. Bureau of Labor Statistics 4  estimated
that  67 pollution control jobs will be gen-
erated for each million dollars of federal ex-
penditure and  evaluated  the feasibility  of
transfering manpower to these jobs from
other areas of science and engineering.
  Chase Econometrics r' predicted that the
expenditures  as estimated by EPA needed
to meet the deadlines of the Clean Air and
the "Federal Water Pollution Control Acts
would increase prices  by annual amounts
reaching a maximum of  1.9 percent in 1976,
thereby slowing economic growth, reducing
the GNP by 2.0 percent, and  increasing un-
employment  by 0.4 percent in 1979.  By
1982, the standards would be met and GNP
and  unemployment would be back  to un-
affected  levels; however,  prices would be
tAvo  percent  higher.  An EPA study "  es-
timated the annual direct cost to industry
associated with the Toxic Substances (
trol Act to be between $79 and  S142
with two-thirds  attributable to premr>
screening  and regulatory  actions and
third attributable to industrial testing
reporting. Dallaire ' reported that the (•
nology needed to achieve the  1983 effl1
limits will be available in most case?
that the  more important  issue is \\lir
the benefits  justify  the  staggering  i
The feeling  within industry   is  that
scheduled rise in standards should  In1
layed because  of the uncertain ecnn
and the  energy situation.   Hayne<
Kleeman8  modeled  the   interaction  •
tween  the  economy and  the  environ;
in the  Coastal  Bend region of Texas
predicted  little inflationary impact  n -
ing from reducing waste  discharges  .1-
quired by national  standards.   John-
suggested that PL  92-500  should  be
vised in order to reduce the cost of at!.
ing environmental quality and relate'!
cial goals by  using the results of comp'1'
Section 208 and other studies to van' ^
quality  standards  according   to re1::
conditions, to vary the means employtv •
water quality control according to rcc1
costs, to deal  uniformly with pollution '•
all sources, and to alter the rules gover
federal financing to encourage adopti"1
least-cost alternatives.
  As part of the continuing interest of •
omists  in environmental  issues,  Tyb''.'
edited a series of readings on the social •
economic implications of environment.'.'
sues that discussed,  among other  too
market biases causing pollution  and •
nomic  alternatives  for   industrial   w •'
treatment.  Krutilla ll summarized the ',.-
ings of the  National Environments !''
gram at Resources for the Future on w"
odologies  for the  economic evaluation
natural resources.
  On the more  practical  side  of emir
mental economics,  Burchell et a/.'2 "'•
lished a standardized approach to the pi'
aration of environmental impact stateim •
to comply with the requirements of the ^
tional Environmental Policy Act (NFF\
for projects including  sewerage and  « r'
treatment systems .  An Institute of Ecol< .
1648   Journal WPCF
                                   2-45

-------
 'udyl3 found that environmental impact
 Mtements would better serve the goals of
 •EPA if they were shortened and written
   emphasize the salient aspects  of project
 •irposes,  benefits,  environmental effects,
  mned mitigation efforts, and major con-
| 'iversies.   Dickson et al.lt  reviewed and
 ''served the use of environmental impact
 'Uements  and reported  that  the  state-
 ments are often inadequate for use in mak-
 ig decisions.  Frequently, the studies are
 mited  in  scope or inadequately defined,
 :e efforts  are poorly  organized and co-
 rdinated, and the methodology adopted is
 nsuited to  the problem at hand.  In com-
 mion  reports, Hill and  Ortolano18 and
 Randolph and Ortolano 18 examined the in-
 "uence  of  NEPA on  federal water  plan-
 "ing and found it to be reasonably effective
 i  generating  information on  direct  im-
 ^acts, but less effective on indirect impacts;
 'he process  overly  emphasizes  particular
 ilternatives and  makes  comparisons  diffi-
 .ult to make, but has generally  improved
 nteragency coordination.
  Ortolano u  rejected economic efficiency
 is  a sufficient criterion for water resources
 planning and discussed how multiple ob-
 ecrive planning did not overcome his ob-
 lections.  He advocated  a planning process
 using public participation in the integration
 of four planning activities: identifying con-
 cerns,  formulating  alternatives,  analyzing
 impact, and ranking  plans.  In  contrast,
 Nash 18  advocated revisions  in cOst-benefit
 analysis procedures  in order  to promote in-
formed public debate by  providing  infor-
 mation  about effects estimated by clearly
stated methods.    From information  ob-
tained from four water  resources planning
studies  in diverse sections of the country,
Priscoli19 found  that planners and citizen
advisory groups often fail to achieve a com-
mon understanding  of their roles; this may
alienate  citizens  if  their once-high  expec-
tations  are  not met.  Water quality was
found  to be the  only  area  in  which the
citizens and planners  consistently shared
perceptions and agreed  on plans.  Richer-
son and Johnston 20 discussed water quality
control objectives from the holistic, recrea-
tion,  scenic, health, and  economic  view-
points and argued  that the difficulties en-
countered in comprehensive water quality
planning are caused  by divergent and in-
commensurable  values  and by incomplete
information.  Gore  et al.21 interviewed 623
residents of the Fall Creek and Canadarago
Lake watersheds in New York to explore
their interest in water  pollution.   They
found widespread concern and willingness
to act or to pay for pollution control pro-
grams, but little real understanding of what
can  be done.   It was concluded  that  any
demonstrably  effective  program would re-
ceive widespread support.
  Krause -2 presented the primary national
water  quality  planning objectives as mini-
mize natural resource waste; protect public
health and ecosystems; provide an imple-
mentable control system;  and permit rapid
decision-making and implementation.   In
addition, the progress of current  planning
efforts toward achieving these goals in the
context of the effects of irrigation in Kansas
on water quality was discussed.  Loucks ~s
evaluated multi-objective  techniques from
the  viewpoint  of  political feasibility  and
proposed use of a technique that would be
able to simulate the bargaining process  and
predict the outcome of the decision-making.
A Technical Committee of the Water  Re-
sources Research Centers  of the 13 Western
States 2* expanded  nine comprehensive so-
cial  goals into  128  measurable social indi-
cators and inverted an  input-output model
matrix for projecting  future values of these
indicators in a  comparison of alternatives
for dealing with water supply and salinity
problems in the Rio Grande Basin in New
Mexico.  Haimes et al.-* reviewed method-
ologies for employing  multiple objectives
in problem solving  and advocated the sur-
rogate-worth tradeoff method  (in  which
the  effects  of  alternatives  on  expressed
goals are presented for  comparison) as one
in which noncommcnsurable objectives can
be handled quantitatively through interac-
tion  between  the  -'ecision-maker  and a
mathematical  moci''i.  Haimes and Hall2B
detailed a particular model  that  handles
multiple objectives expressed  in  noncom-
mensurable  units hv quantifying  tradeoffs
among primary  objectives such as concen-
                                                   -Vol. 48, No. 6, June 1976   1649
                                           2-46

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
LITERATURE REVIEW

tration  reductions  for specific  pollutants
and  secondary  objectives such  as  reduc-
tion  of  algal growth  or achieving a  water
quality  suitable  for swimming. Cohon and
Marks ?7 adopted operational criteria for
mathematical techniques for multi-objective
analysis of water resources projects.  They
determined that a  generating  technique
weighting  the objectives  best captures the
essence of problems  with up to three ob-
jectives; a technique that  restricts  the
size  of  the feasible region such as the sur-
rogate-worth tradeoff method is computa-
tionally more efficient with four or more
objectives.  Taylor et al.M advocated goal
programming (linear  programming to mini-
mize weighted departures from preselected
goals) as preferable to the surrogate-worth
tradeoff method and  the separate consid-
eration  of  environmental  and economic ef-
fects method.   Mercer and  Morgan 29 ap-
plied the VVeibull probability distribution
as a method for evaluating  uncertainty in
four benefit-cost studies.
  Bovet30  provided  planners with a cri-
tique of  the  literature  on  the  economic
aspects  of  water   quality  management
through reviews of the influence of  water
contaminants on various  water uses,  puri-
fication costs,  recycling  costs,  and  tech-
niques  for economic  optimization of treat-
ment systems.   Truett et al.31  developed
planning indices of overall  water  quality,
of the  need for abatement  action, and of
the  need  for water   quality management
planning.   Cumberland   and Stram32 de-
veloped a  materials  balance  accounting
structure to model the waste emission pro-
cess and  advocated follow-up research to
develop emission damage  functions.  Lawr-
ence "jased Los Angeles data and informa-
tion from  previously reported studies  to de-
velop curves for estimating the economic
impact of  supplying  water of varying TDS
content to urban water  users in various
categories.
  Angotti34 analyzed the effectiveness of
regional wastewater treatment systems, us-
ing the Hackensack drainage basin in New
Jersey  as an example, and found that re-
gional systems  preserve higher water qual-
ity  in  headwater streams (because  wastes

1650  Journal  WPCF	
are taken downstream  for treatment) bir!
are less effective  than local systems i.'j
heavily polluted downstream rivers,  Bart--
it ad Gutierrez35 described the Comprehen-
sive Water Quality Management Plannic;
program for  Pennsylvania;  it  covers  L
types  of  point  and   nonpoint  pollute
sources of surface and groundwater anc[
encompasses  alternative environmental  fi>j
tures, financial and institutional design, an:
public participation.  Whipple *" describee'
why water qunlity planning for  the  Del:
ware  estuary  has  been grossly  unsatisfac-
tory  and  advocated regional planning !
meet  specific  environmental  goals in  order
to be more effective and to save billions 01
dollars.  Jensen3T described  fragmented,
programs, diffuse  national leadership, an;
poor  state/federal communications as det-
rimental to water  quality management and
advocated  closer   coordination  of  water
quality control  groups with  both  water:
quantity management and with non-water
environmental programs.  With  a mathe-
matical model for assessing the water sup-
ply alternative for Salt Lake  County,  Utah.
Bishop et aZ.3S  produced  a scheme that]
specified optimal schedules for expansion of;
wastewater treatment plants as part of  thej
total  water resources management for  the!
area.
  Marsden et al.3a outlined the use of dis-
criminant analysis in screening waste  treat-
ment plant cost  data to identify plants thai
are cither exceptionally costly or excep-
tionally cost effective and for analyzing  the
economic  advantage of large-scale regional
waste treatment plants.  Hollman et alS'
analyzed factors contributing to the cost of
managing municipal water systems and to
identified  cost variables  that particularlv
improve management cost effectiveness.
  Hanke et al.tl analyzed the alternatives
and  the Water  Resources  Council recom-i
mendations  for dealing with  inflation in:
economic  analysis and  then  recommended
the use of real prices adjusted as necessarv
for gross changes  in relative values and of
a  real  opportunity  cost discount  rate of
approximately ten percent.   Whipple *2 re-i
viewed alternative approaches to determin-
ing a  discount rate for planning government
                                      2-47

-------
 projects and  concluded  that  there  is  no
 ^asis for using the  relatively high returns
 Stained by investment in private industry,
 'hat discount rates  based on federal bor-
 •Qwing may be too  high  during periods of
 rnpid inflation, and  that a discount rate of
 ive percent  is  reasonable.   Miller and
 Erickson's " examination of the  effect  of
 High interest  rate and such water quality
 parameters  as TS, ss, COD, and Cl~ on the
 design of the  least cost urban drainage sys-
 'em with primary and secondary treatment
 plants showed that  the optimum  design is
 not sensitive  to  the water  quality param-
 eters  but that open ditch  collectors  were
 preferred at high and pipe collectors at low
 discount  rates.  Optimum  holding  pond
 size was  little affected by  any of the pa-
 rameters.
  Swan** generated continued discussion
 by stating that, in terms of  the Coase The-
 orem,  a Pareto  optimum can  be reached
 by bargaining between polluters  and those
 ;hey affect  if the property rights of both
 ire well defined.  Buchanan and Tullock "
 presented a theory of external  control that
 explains the  preference  of  administrators
 for direct pollution control, when most eco-
 nomic  analyses  show penalty taxes  are
 more effective.  Ferrar  et  al.4"  collected
 data on New York City's use of financial  in-
 centives to  promote environmentally  desir-
 able fuels.  The data showed how the legal
 "principle of  fairness,"  requiring uniform
 treatment of  all polluters,  effectively pro-
 hibited  the establishment  of  an optimal
 effluent charge.  Slater"  discussed how
 marginal losses may decrease  rather than
 increase with  increased pollution, how  in
 this situation optimal pollution  control may
 be impossible to achieve by means of taxes
 or other economic  incentives,  and how
 regulatory measures may therefore become
 essential.
  Tulkens  and  Schoumaker48  created  a
pure  exchange  economy  with  two private
 commodities and one  collective externality
 and devised a rule  for adjusting an efflu-
ent charge  to achieve an  optimum.  Bund-
gaard-Nielsen  and  Hwang"  used  linear
programming to show how some  levels  of
effluent  charges can  increase production
                     LITERATURE REVIEW

costs and consumer prices without improv-
ing environmental quality.  In  addressing
the alternatives for centrally reg\ilating in-
dividual behavior  in terms of group inter-
ests, McManus 50 described how the use of
price incentives involves costs in measuring
what  rights are bought and  in  enforcing
bargains that  may cost more  than regula-
tory programs.
  Hyden  et al." simulated  the  mis-alloca-
tion of  waste  discharge levels that results
when conditions change after an  effluent
standard  or  charge  is  established  as a
basin-wide economic optimum.  Kraus and
Mohring52 modeled the use  of  taxes  for
pollution  control  and concluded that  se-
quentially adjusted taxes on both polluters
and victims of  pollution are required  to
achieve optimal waste management.  For-
sund 53  modeled pollution control in a  dy-
namic  setting where environmental harm
depends on previous  as well as  current
waste discharges;  he compared  the infor-
mation  requirements  and  advantages  of
effluent charge  and direct  regulation sys-
tems in this situation.
  Podolick5*  described   the   sewer-use
charge  systems being used  in response to
PL 92-500  guidelines.   The  systems  in-
clude a base  charge proportional to  the
contribution that  normal domestic waste-
water would make to treatment plant load-
ing plus an industrial surcharge  based on
quarterly adjusted estimates of  the addi-
tional cost required to treat  more potent
industrial wastes.   Marshall and Ruegg 5r>
found  in evaluating  current  federal  cost
sharing practices that more efficient pollu-
tion abatement  would result  if  the same
cost sharing  percentages  applied to  all
abatement techniques  and cost  categories.
Two National Bureau of Standards econo-
mists 56  concluded that the  EPA construc-
tion grant program encourages  capital in-
tensive   treatment  technologies   at   the
expense  of technologies  involving  high
labor  costs and  favors industrialized com-
munities over  residential communities.
  Smith 5T developed a  simple  model  for
showing how effluent charges levied on in-
dustrial residuals to reduce  production  ex-
ternalities will induce a production  tech-
                                                  -Vol. 48,  No. 6,  June 1976  1651
                                         2-48

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
LITERATURE REVIEW

nology that improves efficiency evaluation
by reducing  the  nonconvexity of the  pro-
duction relationship.  Wenders38  derived
relationships that show that the incentive to
improve pollution control is greater if pol-
lution taxes are used than  if emission stan-
dards or subsidies are used; emission stan-
dards are  unlikely to be  effective  instru-
ments for inducing improved pollution con-
trol  unless  the  pollution  control  board
promises not to raise its  standards after an
improved technology is adopted.
  McKean  and  Ericson59 viewed water
quality planning in the context of two equi-
librium points: the traditional equilibrium
where marginal  benefits  equal  marginal
cost; and an equilibrium between the ten-
dency  of high water quality  in  recreation
areas to attract  population   and for  that
population to create pollution that reduces
water quality.  Projects should consider the
second  effect as  well as the  first; if  high
water quality is to be achieved, taxation or
zoning policies for population control may
be  required.   Nicolson  and  Mace °°  ap-
proached quantification  of the relationship
between water quality  and recreation use
by  interviewing 240 visitors  to Minnesota
state parks in conjunction  with a program
of water quality sampling and laboratory
analysis  and  recommended   that  water
quality  control  agencies  include  esthetic
degradation to shorelines as an indicator of
water quality for recreation purposes. Rabe
and Hudsonai employed  multiple regres-
sion on Maryland data to examine the effect
of sewer service on urban development pat-
terns and concluded  that, even though their
relationship is not well  defined,  there is a
significant  relationship between  legal ser-
vice areas  and  land  development rates.
DowningS2 stated three propositions for ap-
plying marginal cost pricing of water and
sewer  services and discussed  how such
pricing could be better used to guide urban
development patterns based on the exam-
ples of  Knoxville, Tenn.,  Lexington,  Ky.,
and  Greensboro,  N.  C.    Dornbusch  and
Falcke 83 developed a method for forecast-
ing the effects of water quality enhance-
ment  on  residential property  values  in
terms of distance from the water's edge, a
quantitative  Perceived  Water  Qualiu  h.
de\ developed specially for this pmp.M
public access,  and other factors.   \\ t u.
berger °4 used the dual  solution to a lm< ..
programming model to  show how cmn...,
mental standards can be implemented .::,
ciently  by  using  a  system  of polluti- .
licenses,  performance standards, and /.,:,
ing restrictions.
  Kneese "•'• analyzed the salinity  prohU;..
in the Colorado River in Mexico as a cl.tv..
upstream-downstream conflict  that is piu
ducing an uneconomical approach to rediu
ing salinity in  the Mexicali Valley,  Mas
kusen""  developed an economic m;
to derive an optimal pollution tax strut tun
under these conditions  and to analyze  tin
dependence  and  interaction  between  tl.t
two countries.   It  was  concluded that  u>
operative imposition of national taxes \\ .1',
not  achieve  Pareto  efficiency  without .>
transfer  payment.  Martin67 compiled  fi*
ures showing how improved water manage
ment on the farm can control Color-ul
River salinity at a cost  much less than tlu:
of the proposed desalting plant.  Youns: •:
al.'a  examined the legal and  institutunu;
setting of the present water pollution UM.
trol program in western Colorado  and i -
timated  the  economic  value  of water  i,,.
waste dilution  and the economic  imp.ut.
of programs  to control  saline  irrigation u
turn  flows.   Sekiguchi69 analyzed the  u
lationship  between pollution  levels  .ui.i
economic  activity  in   various  regions <>t
Japan; he  compared impacts  of pollution
controls  or price rises in the iron and  steel
petroleum, and electric  power industries M,
Japan and the U. S. and recommended th.it
international environmental regulation  in-
based on environmental rather than on pol
lution discharge standards.
  Ciccone  et al."°  developed  a model  for
determining the least cost combination of
raw  water sources and renovated waste-
waters ft u-  a municipality using a dual po-
table-nonpotable water  distribution system
Carlson  and  Young T1 used statistical  co>t
and demand functions  and data collected
from  125 southern  cities  to  analyze  the
1652   Journal WPCF-
                                     2-49

-------
  'inomic factors affecting adoption of land
   ttment  of municipal  wastewater; they
j  'ind that federal subsidies were the most
  portant  single  factor  working  against
  -•al adoption of land treatment.  Also  de-
'  • ed  were  elasticities indicating rates at
1  Hich adoption increases with the price of
  •Cation water, the strictness of allowable
  "ram effluent levels, smaller  waste vol-
  •ncs, and dried climate.   Markland et al.~-
  veloped a large-scale mixed integer pro-
 .•.tmming model  that was useful  in per-
  nning benefit-cost analyses for comparing
  'tential land  disposal  wastewater  treat-
  "nt  sites.   Christensen73 examined  the
  >nomic and institutional issues  involved
  land acquisition for and the management
  1 land treatment systems in the context of
  • e goals pursued  by farm managers.
  Singleton  et al.7* employed  a  linear eco-
  unic model of a representative  chlor-alkali
  '.mt to quantify the effects of water qual-
 ••> standards restricting waste discharge of
  \ hardness, and heat on the  cost of chlo-
 ••ne  and caustic  production; they found
 -ist increases ranging up to  12.1  percent
 • >r  zero discharge of  TS from  a mercury
  eil plant.  Stone  et  al.~'J employed a simi-
  ir model  to ethylene production for plas-
 •sc and synthetic fiber and found that zero
 lischarge could be achieved at  an increase
 if 7.0  percent in  production cost and at
 marginal treatment  costs/kg  of $0.88  for
 'S and $1.80 for oil.   linger and Woolver-
 'nn  ;ii used discounted cash flow analysis to
 examine the economic impact of proposed
 Affluent" guidelines on the grain  milling in-
 dustry;  they predicted  that  it  would  be
 minima] because  most of these plants al-
 ready discharge in municipal systems that
 provide adequate  treatment.  Wissman et
 al" assessed the economic impact of pro-
 posed effluent guidelines on the apple,  cit-
 rus, and potato processing industries  and
 predicted  that  products  such  as  canned
 citrus juice  and apple sauce  will  be  se-
 verely  affected.
  Seitz et al.7" found that stream sedimen-
 tation  could be substantially reduced by
 shifting to more intensive cropping patterns /
 in agricultural  areas and  examined regula-
 tory programs, educational efforts, and eco-
                      LlTEHATURE REVIEW

nomic incentives to  farmers to  practice
erosion control.  Heady  and  Nicol79 em-
ployed their model of the agricultural  econ-
omy in the U. S. to examine the  effects  of
soil loss controls on sediment  reduction  as
well  as  on  transport  of  N  and  P  into
streams;  they  also  quantified the  nation-
wide  and regional soil  loss reductions that
could  be  achieved  with various soil loss
standards per acre, the  resulting changes
in tillage  practices by region,  and produc-
tion shifts among regions,  and found that
a standard that would reduce soil loss by a
factor of 3.5  would  increase  commodity
prices by amounts ranging from none for
milk  to 15 percent for soybeans.  Barker
and Nelson s" evaluated the effects of agri-
cultural hind  use patterns and small towns
on  water  quality in the Sheyenne Basin in
North Dakota and the perceptions and at-
titudes of the populace  toward the  prob-
lem.   Everett  and  MillerS1  used  linear
programming and  input-output  models  to
evaluate the  effects  soil erosion control has
on  the economic rate of  timber harvesting
anH found that minimizing soil  loss is not
necessarily the best policy for the economy.
  Rickert et al.s- presented  a framework for
collecting data on the relationship between
economic activity in the Willamette  River
basin and river water  quality.   Nielsen et
al.S3 presented the iterative approach used
in Denmark  for minimizing the  cost of a
water quality sampling program.

REFERENCES
  1.  "Review Draft:  Proposed Report."  National
      Commission on Water  Quality, Washington,
      D. C. (1975).
  2.  Ward, P. S., "NCWQ Released Staff Findings."
      Jour.  Water Poll.  Control Fed., 47, 2350
      (1975).
  3.  Dallaire, G., "U. S. Water  Clean-up Program
      Speeds  Up-But  Still Much Red  Tape."
      Civil Eng., 145, 8, 71 (1975).
  4.  "Impact of  Federal  Pollution  Control  and
      Abatement Expenditures  on Manpower Re-
      quirements."  U. S. Bureau of  Labor Sta-
      tistics, U. S. Govt.  Printing Office,  Wash-
      ington, D. C. (197" ,.
  5.  Chase  Econometric  Asso.,  "The Macroeco-
      nomic Impacts of Federal Pollution Control
      Programs."   Environ.  News  (EPA)  (Jan.
      1975).

	Vol. 48, No.  6, June 1976   1653
                                          2-50

-------
    I
    I
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
y
LITERATURE REVIEW

 (i.  "Draft Economic Impact Assessment  for the   22.
      Proposed  Toxic  Substance  Contiol  Act."
      U.  S.  EPA,  Office of  Toxic  Substances,
      NTLS,  PB 242 826, Springfield, Va. (1975).   23.
 7.  Dallaire.  G., "Will Industry Meet Water Qual-
      ity  Requirements?"  Civil Eng., 145, 12, 68
      (1975;.
 8.  Haynes, K.  E., and Kleeman, W. T., "Environ-
      mental Quality  and Inflation:  A Regional   21.
      Perspective on the Cost-Push  Impact of tht
      1972 Pure Water Legislation."  Environ.  6-
      Planning A (G. B.), 7, 567 (1975).
 9.  Johnson,  R., "President's  Page."  Water Re-
      sources Bull, 11, 5, iii  (1975).
10.  "Environmental Quality and Society." Tybout,
      R. A.  [Ed.], Ohio St. Univ. Press, Columbus   25.
      (1975).
11.  Krutilla,  J. V.,  "The  Economics of Natural
      Environments:  Studies  in the  Valuation  of
      Commodity  and Amenity Resources." Johns   26.
      Hopkins Univ. Press, Baltimore, Md. (1975).
12.  Burchell, R. W., et al.,  "The  Environmental
      Impact Handbook."  Ctr. for Urb. Policy
      Res., Rutgers  Univ., New Brunswick,  N.  J.   27.
       (1975).
13.  "The  Environmental Impact Assessment  Proj-
      ect:  A Critical  Appraisal."   Institute   of
      Ecology, Washington, D. C. (1975).          28.
14.  Dickson,  K. L.,  et al., "Problems in Perform-
      ing Environmental Assessments." /our. Hy-
      draul.  Div., Proc. Amer.  Soc. Civil Engr.,
      101,965 (1975).                            29.
15.  Hill, W. H., and Ortolano,  I.,  "NEPA's In-
      fluence on  Federal Water  Planning:  Part
      1, Effect of  the 'Review and Comment Pro-
      cess' on  the Corps  of Engineers and Soil   30.
      Conservation"  Service."   Progr.  in  Engr.-
      Econ.  Planning,  Stanford Univ.,  Stanford,
      Calif. (1975).
16.  Randolph, ].,  and Ortolano, L.,  "NEPA's In-
      fluence on Federal Water Planning:  Part  2,   31.
      Case Studies  of Corps of Engineers'  Plan-
      ning in California."  Progr.  in Engr.-Econ.
      Planning,  Stanford  Univ.,  Stanford,  Calif.   32.
      (1975).                                     ',•
17.  Ortolano, L., "Water Resources Decision  Mak-
      ing on the  Basis of  the  Public  Interest."
      U. S. Army Engr. Inst. for Water Resources,
      75-1,  Fort Belvoir, Va. (1975).
18.  Nash, ~C.,  "An  Evaluation  of  Cost-Benefit   33.
      Analysis Criteria." Scottish jour. Pol. Econ.,
      22, 121 (1975).
19.  Priscoli, J.  D.,  "Citizen Advisory Groups and
      Conflict Resolution in Regional WaU-r Re-   34.
      sources Planning."   Water Resources  Bull.,
      11, 1233 (1975).
20.  Richerson,  P.,  and  Johnston,   R., "Environ-   35.
      mental Values and Water Quality Planning."
      /our.  Hijdraul. Div., Proc. Amer. Soc. Civil
      Engr., 101,259  (1975).
21.  Core, P,  H., et  al, "A Sociological Approach   36.
      to the  Problem of Water Pollution."  Growth
      and Change, 6, 17 (1975).
Krause, K. S.,  "Objectives  ot  \V,itt .  i.°
  Planning."  Jour. Hijdraul. Dit , I'* •
  Soc. CiiAl Knur., 101, 471 (1975
Loucks, D. P ,  'Conflict and Chou.   i
  tor Multiple  Objectives "  ECUIMH.,
  Models  and Development Plamuii-. (
  xt-r ft al. [Eds.], Oxford Um\, hi-,   '
  York, 1975.
"WatIT Hesoiirci-.s Planning, Social ( .-.i!
  Indicators.    Methodological   I )< > .  '
  and Empirical Test."  The Tedum  i.  l
  imttee  of  tin-  Water Resource-.  Iv
  Centers   ot  the Thirteen  West, in  -••
  Utah Water  Res.  Lab.,  Utah  Stau  '
  Logan ( 1974)
Haunt's, Y. Y.,  ft al., "Multiobjectue  t>,
  zation  in Water  Resources Ssst.  ia-
  scvier   .Scientific  Pub,   Co.,  An,si
  ( 1975).
Haimes, Y. Y.  and Hall, W. A.,  "Aiuh-
  Multiple  Objectives  in  Water  Oiui
  /our.  llydratil.  Div., Proc.  Amur.  S«,  i
  Engr., 101, 387 (1975).
Cohon,  J.   L.,  and Marks,  D. H., "A H
  and Evaluation of  Multiobjectne- I1:, .
  ming Techni(iues."  Water Rvsourin  :
  11, 208  (1975).
Taylor, B. W., HI, et al., "Approaches t.i VI
  tiobjective Planning in Water RCSOIIKI  i
  ects."    Water  Resources Bull.,  11
  ( 1975).
Mercer, L. J., and Morgan,  W. D., "E\.ii .,•
  of  a  Probability  Approach to V'ni. :i .
  in Benefit-Cost Analysis."  Water H. v
  Ctr., Univ. of California, Davis  i U)T"
Bovet, E.  D., "Evaluation  of Quaht\ 1'.
  eters in Water  Resource  Planning i  \  •»•
   of-the-Art  Survey of the Economus i,t \
  ter Quality)."  U.  S. Army  Enur.  Ii,-i
  Water Resources, Fort BeKoir,  \'a   ',
Truett, J.  B., ct  al., "Development ,.t \\
  Quality  Management Indices."   U a'.. •
  vouiw.s  Bull., 11, 436 ( 1975).
Cuml)erland,  J. H..  and Strain,  B  N   i .•
  of Economic Development Upon \\ it.
  sources   (An  Interindustry  Appiu.,, :.
  Modeling  Economic-Environmental
  terns)''  Bur. of Bus. and Econ. IU_i  M
  land Univ., College Park (1974).
Lawrence, C.  H., "Estimating Indirect  t
  of Urban Water Use." /our.  Environ  i •
  Div., Proc. Amer. Soc. Civil Engr., UU
  (1975).
Angotti, T. R., "Planning for Regional V.,
  Water  Systems."  Growth and Chun^
   36 (1975).
Bartal, K.  A., and Gutierrez,  L. V , ]r. ' (
  prehensive   Water   Quality   Man.i«i ,
  Planning."  /our. Hijdraul. Div., Proc  \
  Soc. Cioil Engr., 101, 371 (1975).
Whipple,  W.,  Jr.,  "Water Quality  PLan
  for  the Delaware  Estuary."   Wafer
  sources  Bull., 11, 300 (1975).
     1654   Journal WPCF-
                                               2-51

-------
53.
54.
 Jensen, E. T., "Problems in Integrating Wa-
   ter Programs."  Jour. Hi/tlraul. Div.,  Proc.
   Amer. Soc.  Civil Engr., 101, 467 (1975).
^Bishop, A.  B., "Economic  Assessment of  an
   Activity Analysis  Model  for Water Supply
   Planning."  Water Resources Res.,  11, 783
   (1975).
 Marsden,  J. R., et al.,  "The Large-Scale Re-
   gional Plant Hypothesis: Discriminant Anal-
   ysis."   Water  Resources Res., 11,  1013
   (1975).
 Hollman,  K. W., et al.,  "Methods to Facilitate
   Managerial  Effectiveness  in Municipal Wa-
   ter Systems."  Water Resources Res.  Inst,
   Mississippi State Univ., Starkville (1975).
 Hanke, S. H., et al., "Project Evaluation Dur-
   ing  Inflation."   Water Resources Res.,  11,,-
   511  (1975).
 Whipple,  VV.fl, Jr., "Principles of Determining
   a  Social Discount Rate."   Water Resources
   Bull, 11, 811 (1975).
 Miller, W. L., and Erickson, S. P., "The Im-
   pact  of  High Interest Rates on Optimum
   Multiple Objective Design of Surface Runoff
   Urban Drainage Systems." Water Resources
   Bull., 11, 49 (1975).
 Swan,  P.  L.,  "The Coarse Theorem  and 'Se-
   quential'  Pareto Optimality."   The Econ.
   Record (Austl.), 51, 268  (1975).
 Buchanan, J.  M.,  and Tullock, G., "Polluters'
   Profits and  Political Response: Direct Con-
   trols Versus Taxes."  The Amer. Econ. Re-
   vieio, 55, 139 (1975).
 Ferrar, T. A.,  et al., "Effluent Charges and Po-
   litical Realities—A Qualification." Jour. En-
   viron. Systems, 5, 97  (1975).
 Stater, M., "The Quality of Life and the Shape
   of Marginal Loss  Curves."   The Economic
   Jour. (G. B.), 85,  864 (1975).
 Tulkens,  H.,  and  Schoumaker, F., "Stability
   Analysis of  an Effluent Charge and  the 'Pol-
   luters Pav' Principle."  Jour, of  Public Eco-
   nomics  ( Neth.), 4, 215 ( 1975).
 Bundgaard-Nielson,  M., and  Hwang, C.  L.,
   "On  Taxation and Firms Choice of Waste
   Water Treatment Technology."   Water Re-
   sources Bull.. 11, 805 ( 1975).
 McManus, J.  C.,  "The Costs  of Alternative
   Economic Organizations." Can.  Jour. Econ.,
   8, 334 (1975).                            /
 Ilvden, J.  W.. et al.,  "Simulation of Water/
   Quality  Management  Policies "  Jour.  En-
   viron. £ngr. Div., Proc.  Amer.  Soc.  Civil
   Fns,r., 101,  623  (1975).
 Kram,  M.,  and Mohring,  H.,  "The  Role of '
   Pollutee Taxes  in Externality  Problems."
   Economica  (G. B.), 42. 171  (1975).
 Forsnng, F. R., "The Polluter P;us Principle
   and  Transitional Period Measures in a Dy-
   namic Setting."   The Swed.  Jour, of Econ.,
   77, 56 (1975).
 Podolick,  P.  A.,  "An  Equitable  Sewer Use
   Charge  System."   Pub.  U'orfcs.   106,  9!
   (1975).
                         LITERATURE  REVIEW

55. Marshall,  H.  E., and  Ruegg, R. T .  "Analysis
      of  Cost Sharing   Programs   for  Pollution
      Abatement of Municipal Wastev uter."  Nat.
      Bur. of Srds.. U. S.  Govt. Printing Office,
      Washington, D. C.  ( 1974).
56. "Cost Sharing to Help Clean Our Waterways."
      U. S. National Bureau of Standards, Dimen-
      sion* NBS, 58, 267  (1974).
57. Smith, V.  K., "Detrimental Externalities, Non-
      convexities and  Technical  Change."  Jour.
      of  Public   Economics   (Neth.),   4,   289
      (1975).
58. Wenders,  J. T., "Methods  of Pollution Control
      and  the Rate of  Change in Pollution Abate-
      ment Technology."   Water Resources Res.,
      11, .393 (1975).
59. McKean, J. R., and Ericson, R. K.,  "Quality of
      Life and   Environmental  Social  Overhead
      Impact."   Water Resources  Res.,  11,  789
      (1975).
60. Nicolson, J. A., and Mace, A. C.,  Jr., "Water
      Quality Perceptum.  by  Users:  Can  It  be
      Supplement Objective Water  Quality Mea-
      sures?"   Water  Resources Bull.,  11, 1197
      (1975).
61. Rabe, F. T., and Hudson, f F.,  "Highway  and
      Sewer   Impacts  on  Urban  Development."
      Jour. Urban Plan. 6- Dev. Div., Proc. Amer.
      Soc. Civil Engr., 101,  217 (1975).
62. Downing,  D. A., "Sewer  and  Water Pricing
      and  Investment  Policies  to Implement  Ur-
      ban Growth Policy." Water Resources Bull.,
      11, 345 (1975).
63. Dombusch,  D. M.,  and  Falcke,  C. O,   "A
      Generic Methodology to  Forecast Benefits
      from Urban Water Resource  Improvement
      Projects."   David  M. Dornbusch  and Co.,
      San  Francisco, Calif. (1971).
64. Werczberger, E..  "Urban  Land-Use  Planning
      and  Environmental  Pollution."  Environ. 751.
69. Sekiguchi, S., "Environmental Regulations jnd
      Japan's  Industry and  International Trade."
      Jap.  Econ.  Studies, 3,  4, 83 (1975).
70. Ciccone,  V  J.,  et  al., "A  Present  Value-Unit
      Cost Methodology  for Evaluating Munici-
                                                          -Vol.  48, No. 6, June 1976   1035
                                                 2-52

-------
I
I
I
 I
 I
 I
  I
  I
   I
   I
   I
   I
    I
    I
    I
     I
     I
     I
      I
      LITERATURE REVIEW

            pal Wastewater Reclamation and Direct Re-
            use." Water Resource;, Bull., 11, 21 (1975).
      71. Carlson, C. A., and Young, C. E., "Factors Af-
            fI/., ting  Adoption of  Land Treatment  of
            Municipal  Waste Wattr."  Water Resources
            &•*., 11, 616 (1975).
      72. Mainland, R.  E., et d., "A Benefit-Cost Anal-
            ysis  of Alternative  Land  Disposal Waste
            Water Methods in an Urban Environment."
            School of Bus. Adm., Univ. of Missouri,  St.
            Louis (1974).
      73. Chmtensen, L. A., "A P .imework for Evaluat-
            ing  Institutional ante Water."  ]our.
            Environ. Quality, 4,  i-i5  i 1975).
      74. Singleton, F.  D., Ji.,  et  al., "An Integrated
            Power Process  Model  of  Water Use  and
            Waste  Water  Treatment  in  Chlor-Alkali
            Production."  Water Resources Res., 11. 515
            (1975).
      75. Stone, J. C., et al., "An Integrated Power Pro-
            cess Model for Ethylene Production."  Wa-
            ter Resources Res., 11, 810 (1975).
      76. Unger, S. G., and Woolverton, M. W., "Eco-
            nomic Analysis of Effluent Guidelines: Grain
            Processing Segment  of  the Grain Mills In-
            dustry."   Development  Planning and  Re-
            search Asso., Inc., Manhattan, Kan. (1975).
      77. Wissman, D. ]., et al., "Economic Analysis of
            Effluent Guidelines:  Apple, Citrus  and Po-
            tato Processing Segments of the Canned and
            Preserved  Fruits and Vegetable Industry."
            Development Planning and Research Asso.,
            Inc., Manhattan, Kan. (1975).
      78. Seitz,  W. D., et al.,  "Evaluation  of  Agricul-
            tural Policy Alternatives to Control Sedi-
            mentation."  Illinois Water Resources Ctr.,
            Univ. of 111., Urbana-Champaign (1975).
      79. Heady, E.  O., and Nicol, K.  J.,  "Models of
            Land and Water Allocation to Improve En-
            vironment  and Water Quality Through Soil
            Loss Controls."  Water Resources Res., 11,
            795 (1975).
      80. Barker, W.  T., and Nelson,  W.  C., "Lower
            Sheyenne River Basin:  Water,  Land, Peo-
            ple."  Water  Resources  Res.  Inst.,  North
            Dakota St. Univ., Fargo, 1974.
      81. Everett, H.  W., II, and  Miller, W. L., "Sec-
            toral and Regional Economic Impact of Con-
            trolling  Nonpoint   Pollution in  Forested
            Areas."  Water Resources Res. Ctr., Purdue
            Univ., W. Lafayette  (1975).
      82. Rickert, D. A., et al, "Methods and Data Re-
            quirements  for River-Quality Assessment."
            Water Resources Bull, 11,  1013 (1975).
  /
'/    83. Nielsen, K. S., et al., "A Note on Cost-Effec-
            tiveness in Data Acquisition in Water Qual-
            ity Management."   Water Resources  Res.,
            11, 357 (1975).
      1656   Journal WPCF-

                      2-53

-------
Economics
L. D. James
Utah State University, Logan

  The final report of the National Commission
on Water Quality 1 recommended a  number of
"mid-course adjustments" so that the adminis-
tration of  the  Water Pollution Control Act of
1972  (PL 92-500) would restore the integrity
of the nation's waters.  The recommendations,
formulated from  a long  series of studies,  in-
cluded  postponing  certain  requirements,  in-
creasing administrative  decentralization  and
flexibility, and  redefining goals  to emphasize
the conservation and reuse of limited resources
rather than waste discharge elimination. The
Environmental Sciences sector of the National
Commission on Water Quality 2 sponsored  41
river basin studies, covering the entire nation,
to characterize present  environmental  condi-
tions  and project biological,  ecological,  and
environmental benefits  from  effluent  loading
reductions and water quality changes.  In a
summary  volume, Allen et al.3  outlined  the
study methodology,  projected  impacts from
abatement of point source  loadings, and sum-
marized the findings.  A second volume pre-
sented such special topics as an evaluation of
water quality models,  the  state-of-the-art  of
projecting ecological change, and  a review of
existing water quality data systems.
  A study by the Human Resources  Planning
Institute * found that the primary  and second-
ary economic impacts of the  1972  Act  will
generate more  jobs  for  middle-income white
males and reduce job opportunities for females,
older  workers, and others in low-income cate-
gories.  An analysis by the Public  Research
Institute 5 of  the effects of the Water Pollution
Control  Act of  1972 on seven industries (iron
and steel, aluminum, copper, textiles, pulp and
paper, and leather tanning and red meat) with
high pollution abatement costs predicted con-
sequent increased import penetrations of these
industries of 1.5 to 6 percent.  The total effect
on domestic industry was expected to be small
because the volume of  trade  was small com-
pared to domestic production.  An analysis of
the Act's effects on the dairy  industry by De-
velopment Planning  and Research Associates "
indicated that the 1983  requirements  will  re-
duce  the net  income of large plants by 30 per-
cent and smaller plants  by 50  percent.  Ap-
proximately  1 plant in  18  will be  forced to
close, and prices  will increase by  1.4 percent.
An analysis 7 on  the effects on  the fruit and
vegetable processing industry found that  the
greatest price increases  (up to about 0.3 per-
cent) will be required by smaller plants in  the
corn,  tomato, and sauerkraut sectors and that
the greatest number of  plant closures because
of difficulty in paying  required pretreatment
costs will occur among Florida citrus plants and
potato dehydrating plants in the Pacific  North-
west. The same  firm s also compared costs for
17 technologies for pollution control from beef,
turkey,  dairy, and hog feedlots  and estimated
                                               2-54

-------
   I
   I
   I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
i
Literature  Review
that  the greatest  expenditure will be required
for hog lots and that the greatest price impact
(about 1  percent)  will be  on  turkey and
dairy lots.  An estimated 37 000 to 77 000 lots
will be forced to close by 1977.
   Lusky 9 used a model developed for allocat-
ing resources among original production, pro-
duction of recycled goods, and waste disposal
to show how in cases, like water, where refuse
markets are not forthcoming that governmental
intervention is necessary for pollution control.
Macauley  and Yandle10 noted  a  consistent
record  of failure for  managing water quality
by regulation and government expenditure and
recommended trying a system wherein stream
responsibility (like land ownership) is sold to
the highest bidder and  the  proceeds are used
to finance  public  programs.    Marshall and
Ruegg's analysis " of the current  practice  of
equal  division of user fees  collected from in-
dustrial waste discharges between the munici-
pality  and the federal government  concluded
that the policy was causing significant efficiency
distortions  that could be eliminated  by return-
ing all collected fees to  the  U. S. Treasury.
   McMillan 12  argued that separate environ-
mental authorities  for  water, air,  and  land
pollution control  can more  effectively protect
the public interest than can  a single overall
agency because the multijurisdictional arrange-
ment reduces the adverse effects of the vote
trading that occurs within a single governing
body.  Tomasini " presented a concept of fair-
ness  (illustrated  by numerical example) for
use  in allocating pollution loadings among
waste  dischargers.   Levi  and  Beattie14  de-
scribed a  case in which a Texas  court had
awarded  damages equalling the loss caused to
a rancher by upstream pollution and cited this
liability for inadvertent downstream pollution
damages  as a departure  from past court rulings
and a positive step toward economic equity.
   Williams and Rucks 15 outlined  the financial
dilemma  placed on municipalities required to
provide waste  treatment  facilities costing  an
average of $ 1500 per  person and  advocated
that  the  situation in each city be studied in-
dividually  to  estimate pollution  control  costs
and identify funding sources and financial im-
pacts.   Boyd et a/.18 reviewed  the nutrient
loading of the Missouri River near Kansas City
in the  context of available  treatment methods
and  found that complete nutrient removal at
wastewater treatment facilities  would  be  a
waste  of  money.
   Among the new books published, Quarles 1T
made a strong case for a greater pollution con-
trol effort,  and Caldwellia  described the role
citizens can take  to enhance the environment.
Hammer la assessed  the  social implications  of
abatement  alternatives  while Dimento20  an-
alyzed the problems in achieving the behavioral
changes required  for a higher quality environ-
ment.  Andrews J1 examined the effectiveness
of the National Environmental  Policy Act  in
achieving these changes.   Finally,  Kneese -2
outlined  the role of economics in  choosing
among environmental management alternatives
and in providing  incentives to achieve desired
goals.
  Stephens 23 used a general neoclassical model
of growth and pollution to show how technical
progress can provide exponential growth of per
capita income within  the context of improving
environmental quality. To do so, the marginal
productivities of new technology to limit waste
discharge and  to augment  environmental  ab-
sorptive  capacity should be equalized.   Lip-
nowski •*  employed  input-output analysis  to
gauge the  potential for economic  growth  in
the presence of  a  requirement  for complete
environmental preservation and to estimate the
rate of profit an industry operating without any
environmental restrictions would have to have
for profitable operation to continue if environ-
mental controls were imposed. Uri's analysis 2S
of the effects  of environmental  quality stan-
dards on the power generating industry showed
an incentive toward larger investment in new
generating  capacity in part  caused  by  pre-
mature retirement of existing capacity.
  Eidem 26 described the role of the Swedish
Water and Air Pollution Research Laboratory
(IVL) in water pollution  control in  Sweden.
Swedish  industry will have to invest annually
an amount  equal to about  2  percent of  the
value of goods  manufactured for pollution con-
trol,  but twice that  investment would be  re-
quired  to  meet  all  of  society's  demands.
Whipple'" proposed  that the U. S. change a
current water pollution control policy  that  re-
quires treatment at all cost and uniform quality
standards in order  to pursue basic  environ-
mental  quality  objectives   more  effectively.
Three needed revisions would be to refocus  on
achievable  goals,  to coordinate river water
quality management with flow regulation, and
to make  real use  of planning results.  Whipple
and  Hufschmidt28  reported  workshop recom-
mendations  for  priority  emphasis  in water
quality control  research on evaluating die costs
of environmental  and social impacts, on defin-
ing  additional control  alternatives  so as  to
broaden  the base of those considered, and  on
1538   Journal WPCF
                                         2-55

-------
                                                                         Literature Review
improving the efficiency of water quality con-
trol institutions.
  Friesema  and  Culhane's  analysis2"  of  the
effects of the National Environmental Policy
Act of 1969 on water resources planning noted
an increasing emphasis on public participation,
staff hiring of individuals from a broader range
of professional backgrounds, and greater effort
to ameliorate  adverse environmental impacts.
Wengert30  used  an  analysis  of the growing
pressures for public  participation  in resource
management to begin an effort to develop  a
theory of the public participation process that
is harmonious with both democratic ideals and
pragmatic experience.  Tideman and Tullock 31
described a  process of offering each individual
a chance to change  the outcome that would
occur  without  his vote by paying  a  special
charge set equal to the net effect on others of
his vote as a  mechanism for motivating in-
dividuals to reveal their  true  preferences for
public goods.
  Lienesch  and Emison 32 reviewed the area-
wide water quality planning program underway
under Section 208, PL 92-500, and despite en-
countered   problems  in  resolving  conflicts
among interest groups, achieving effective in-
stitutional arrangements, and  identifying cost
effective approaches concluded that the high-
lighting of issues for  public discussion resulting
within the  planning  process  is itself an  im-
portant step toward  improved water  quality
management.   Grantham  and Bailey33  de-
scribed how water quality plans  were being
formulated to meet federal and state legal re-
quirements  in  the California  Water  Quality
Control Planning Basins.
  Bundgaard-Nielsen  and Hwang's review34
of the literature  on  regional  water  quality
management  classified  available   planning
models according to whether  their  orientation
was  toward  centralized planning, diffuse deci-
sion   making,  or  multiple objectives.   Mc-
Namara35 developed  and illustrated  through
numerical example a geometric nonlinear pro-
gramming model for simultaneous consideration
of waste treatment  processes, bypass  piping,
flow regulation, and  artificial  aeration in  de-
termining the  least-cost water  quality manage-
ment program for the upper Hudson River.
Bovet38  synthesized  several earlier  reports in
developing planning guidelines for water qual-
ity management through  optimization balanc-
ing  the cost of enhancement  against benefit.
The  economic  efficiency  of water  reuse and
acid mine drainage control were also discussed.
  Rohrlich 3T contributed an extended descrip-
tion of how economic and social factors  can be
integrated in environmental management. Gum
et al.38 illustrated  the Techcom system  for
weighting social preferences for esthetics, eco-
nomics, and recreation from answers to a mail
questionnaire  in  Arizona  and  New Mexico.
Use  of the Metfessel general allocation  test
provided usable information for comprehensive
evaluation  of  natural  resource  management
policies.   Phillips and DeFilippi39 developed
a method for comparing environmental impacts
of alternative wastewater management systems
that  tabulates environmental impacts with re-
spect to identified objectives and collapses the
resulting  matrix into  a  numerical   impact
measure,
  Hipel et al.*0 presented metagame theory as
a nonquantitative or descriptive  approach for
considering information that cannot readily be
expressed in  quantitative form  together  with
quantitative data to evaluate conflict situations,
such  as  international pollution  disputes,  in
which decision-making does not conform to the
classical assumption of rational behavior. Hipel
et al.*1 also illustrated metagame analysis as  a
means for identifying possible political solutions
for controlling water pollution from a steel mill.
Ragade et  a/.*2 demonstrated how stable com-
promise possibilities between diverse  interest
groups can be defined  by having each group
assign values  to benefits and costs from  their
viewpoint  and by  applying  meta rationality
concepts   to   the   resulting   pseudo-boolean
functions.
  Van Praag  and  Linthorst43 used  returned
questionnaires  from  responsible  municipal
officials in  550 of 842  Dutch communities to
derive municipal welfare  functions for  each
one.    Public  works  expenditures  per  capita
were  quantified as decreasing  with community
size,  reaching a point where  diseconomies of
scale begin to predominate, and then increasing
for still larger communities at an elasticity with
respect  to  inhabitants of  1.4.   Trigg  et al.**
used Winnipeg attitude survey data to confirm
the hypothesis that individuals who believe that
their  rewards  depend on  their  own abilities
were  better informed on  pollution problems
than are other people.
  Brill  et  al." illustrated  for  the  Delaware
Estuary how application of the equity  criteria
that equals should be treated equally and that
non-equals should be treated differently results
in a  much lower pollution control  cost  than
does a program of uniform treatment standards
for  each pollutant  and concluded that even
                                         2-56
                                                                          June 1977   1539

-------
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
application of  equity  criteria with  imperfect
information  can lead  to policy-improving in-
sights.  Brumm and Dick46 reviewed current
Federal Water  Pollution Control policy and
concluded that  regulatory  programs, bargain-
ing strategies,  and effluent changes  alike re-
quire an almost impossibly expensive research
program to obtain the information needed for
optimal design  and  that a system of setting
standards and raising the charges as necessary
to achieve them is  overall much more  cost-
efficient.  Herzog "  assessed the relative effi-
ciency  and  equity  for the  Patuxent  River
(Maryland) of charges set to achieve a  water
quality  standard at minimum cost when both
plant treatment costs and residual transfer costs
are known,  when  only the transfer  costs are
known,  and when neither are known  (an equal
per unit charge to all discharges). He  found
significant  efficiency  gain  from  information
availability but no  impressive real resource cost
savings.  Dick ** synthesized from the  litera-
ture critical to the  Coase theorem that bilateral
bargaining in a voluntary,  frictionless setting
produces optimality only by accident.  Because
of the  facts that  the  placement of liability
affects  resource allocation  and  that liability
assigned by  voluntary bargaining  cannot be
expected to produce optimal solutions  to ex-
ternality problems,   such  nonvoluntary  ap-
proaches as zoning, standards, prohibitions, or
taxes are  required  to  achieve  optimality.
Mathur *9 showed how a spatially variable
pollution tax charged  to a firm  that may re-
spond either by reducing its waste disposal or
moving to another location subject to less tax
will  not necessarily encourage the dispersal of
industries having  alternative abatement  tech-
nologies from highly polluted areas.
   Bundgaard-Nielsen's  analysis 50 of  how the
influences of  available  technology  and eco-
nomic incentives interact in a firm's wastewater
treatment investment decisions concluded that
subsidy will induce new investment when the
subsidy offered exceeds the cost less the ac-
cruing  savings  divided  by the  interest rate.
DeWees and Sims " explained  why  subsidies
paid  to reduce  emissions are not symmetrical
to effluent  charges  as  instruments  for con-
trolling  pollution because of technical problems
in establishing a base  emission at which the
subsidy begins, effects caused by firm entry and
exit  from the industry, and market distortions
caused  by unavoidable subsidy discontinuities.
Any financial relief required to help firms con-
trol  emission should be in the  form of lump
sum  payments based  on  past  production.
Smith " developed a simple model to  demon-
strate that efficient resource  allocation in the
presence  of  product market  distortions  and
pollution externalities requires both an output
subsidy and effluent charges.   More generally,
the number  of  policy  instruments should at
least equal the number of imperfections to be
corrected.
  Orr 53 described how, despite the literature
on the difficulties in achieving economic  effi-
ciency  through  user charges, experience has
shown  (largely because of robustness  in spite
of incomplete information) charges to be effec-
tive, their effectiveness  to increase  with time,
and their  impact to  have not been excessively
disruptive.  Emphasis was placed on  the im-
portance of reckoning effectiveness in terms of
innovative incentives as well as the more tradi-
tional  allocation  efficiency.   Holtermann5*
showed that  when externalities cannot be di-
rectly  taxed,  Pareto optimality  can  still be
achieved by  taxing outputs whose production
produced  the externality,  or  by  taxing  pro-
ducers of inputs  whose use in the production
process generates  the externality.  Compensa-
tion paid to the victims of the externality  does
not affect Pareto optimality unless the victims
can influence the compensation rates. Through
a survey of 177 South Carolina municipalities,
Mulkey and Stepp " found that the prevailing
practices of flat rate or water bill percentage
sewer  charges are unlikely to satisfy the  EPA
criterion of charging proportional to treatment
cost and recommended further study to formu-
late  a  charging  vehicle that  can satisfy this
equity  criterion  without  requiring costly in-
strumentation.
  Ehler et al.i& identified through  a residuals
management model the points in the residuals
gfneration and  discharge process  at which
physical action, laws or regulations, and better
institutional  arrangements  can  be effectively
used to reduce adverse environmental effects.
From  the simulated consequences  of water
quality management through  effluent  charges,
effluent standards, and  effluent treatment sub-
sidies,  Campbell " demonstrated that  the re-
sulting income distributional effects depend on
both the policy instrument and the level of the
jurisdiction administering it, and therefore ad-
vocated individual design of an appropriate
policy  instrument for each  local  situation.
Keith et al.™ were not able to establish  a causal
relationship between water quality controls and
income distribution by  fitting a beta distribu-
tion  function to  SMSA  data  and testing the
significance  of changes.  Edwards  and Lang-
 1540  Journal WPCF
                                         2-57

-------
ham 58 used a model with a nonlinear objective
function and linear  environmental constraints
on  externalities  not  quantifiable in monetary
terms to estimate that a 50 percent reduction
in usage  of  chlorinated hydrocarbons would
reduce welfare, estimated as consumers surplus
plus producers  surplus, by  about  1  percent
and that elimination of their usage would re-
duce welfare by about  3 percent.
  Asch and Seneca's  examination80  of  the
conflict between the  adverse welfare impact of
monopoly and the  environmental benefit  of
internalizing  externalities within a monopoly
for  the case of the automobile industry showed
how undesirable consequences will result with-
out  coordination between  environmental and
antitrust policies,  with  the  optimal  balance
depending on  the  monopolist's  extra  profit
margin  and marginal cost the  externality in-
flicts on others.  Cowing 6X employed a  two-
input, two-output process model to demonstrate
how effluent charges or a polluting monopoly
already constrained by rate-of-return regulation
may have either a  favorable  or  an  adverse
social impact.  He  argued that the policy for
dealing with each such monopoly  should  be
specifically designed from detailed knowledge
of its production process and the effects of its
externalities on others.
  Peskin 82 examined four  alternatives for ad-
justing  estimates of the GNP  for pollution
effects and found an adjustment equal to the
net value of environmental assets to be best for
environmental management purposes, the sub-
traction of residual damage to provide  the best
welfare measure, the addition of the net value
of environmental asset services to provide the
best index of total production, and no adjust-
ment at all to provide the best index of human
productive services.  Sandier and Smith 63 ap-
plied a "reference group" concept to show how
Pareto  efficiency,  maximization of each in-
dividual's utility summed over  individuals and
time, in the allocation  of  environmental re-
sources over time  or among  generations re-
quires that  each person's incremental  benefits
from a public good be treated equally, regard-
less of the time they  receive the benefits, rather
than be discounted  at  a constant  rate for  all
individuals  and time  periods.   White64  ob-
served that economists have a long established
taxonomy for analyzing market failure but have
never  analyzed nonmarket failure  systemati-
cally.  The three principal nonmarket failures
in the context of water pollution control were
a failure to properly recognize  the  limitations
of  governmental structure in  assigning func-
tional responsibility, a failure to act in ways
that equitably  distribute  the benefits,  and  a
failure  to  obtain  and  use  the  proper  in-
formation.
  Dworsky et aJ.65 reported  the recommenda-
tions of a workshop that examined  the inter-
action  between water quality and land  use
planning for  the purpose of proposing policy
changes  to  enhance  conflict  resolution  and
management efficiency. Specific recommenda-
tions vvere made in the areas  of program evalu-
ation, investment  strategies,  and  institutional
arrangements.   Bammi et al.M  described  ap-
plication of a model siting urban land develop-
ment  to  minimize aggregate adverse environ-
mental impact  (including water pollution) to
suburban  Chicago.  Black,  Crow, and Eids-
ness, Inc.87  found that a suitable  technology
for  abating urban  storm water pollution is yet
to be developed and that nationwide abatement
to a level equivalent  to  secondary  treatment
would cost approximately 160 billion dollars.
  Walter 8S edited a volume of 15 papers on
applications  of economics to international is-
sues in environmental management. Individual
papers  reached such  conclusions  that large
countries applying pollution  control measures
unilaterally can expect an improvement in the
balance of trade  that will help pay  for  the
system  and  that special  regulation of multi-
national corporations is unnecessary unless the
adverse  environmental  consequences  physi-
cally cross international borders.  Pethig " ap-
plied  a  two-sector general equilibrium model
to  international  trade among  nations with
potentially  varying  environmental  policy to
derive  five theorems relating to the effects of
trade  on  the   environment  in each country.
Differences in  national environmental policies
were found to  not generally  imply differences
in national environmental qualities.
  Dornbusch et al.~9 concluded that the effect
of  water pollution  abatement  on  property
values  depends on lay perceptions of conse-
quences for wildlife support, recreational  op-
portunity, and esthetics.   An analysis of  17
sites showed greater effects  on  lakes than on
streams and on larger bodies of water than on
smaller.  Klee  71 presented an additive utility
model for setting  priorities based on environ-
mental threat for dealing with waste discharges
and requiring selection of criteria, measurement
of parameters,  assignment of ratings, and  de-
termination and combination of values.
  Teniere-Buchot ™  outlined the role that the
public has taken in development of the Fiench
water quality  control and related water man-
                                                                          June 1977  1541
                                          2-58

-------
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
agement p ograms.  Seifert and Lyons 7S de-
scribed   four   approaches  under   legislative
consideration for using economic incentives to
reduce  wastewater discharges in  West  Ger-
many.   The  approaches are to establish sep-
arate  river  basin  wastewuter  management
associations with individual  charging  rules,
accumulate collected charges in financial re-
serves  to  pay  for treatment  facilities,  allow
claims  against  the  reserves  when treatment
facilities are completed, and uniform charging
according to effluent harmfulness based on the
average cost of full biological  treatment. John-
son and Brown 71 described the use of effluent
charges  and  abatement  subsidies in  water
quality management systems in France,  Neth-
erlands,  West  Germany,  Hungary, Sweden,
and  England  and concluded that since no
pollution  abatement program in the world is
free  of subsidies, the management  choice may
be between a second best program with sub-
sidies and an ineffective program without them.
Laburn 75  reviewed  the water quality control
and related water resources management efforts
of the  Rand Water Board,  Republic of  South
Africa,  over  the last 70  years  and discussed
such measures  as separate disposal of  mine
effluent,  agricultural, industrial, and  potable
use of wastewater effluent,  dual water supply
systems,  and piping high quality upstream
water to downstream areas.
  After  describing water pollution problems
found in large cities in tropical Africa,  Onoker-
horaye 76 emphasized that developing countries
should not automatically adopt the standards of
the more advanced nations  (a policy destined
to widespread failure) but should rather estab-
lish  an  administrative structure that can  solve
priority problems with available financial re-
sources  and expertise.   GruverT? employed
a neoclassical growth model in an analysis of
the  optimal  division of  investment between
pollution control capital and production capital
for less  developed "countries  that  showed an
optimal sequence of first emphasizing expansion
of production  capital  (despite  the increased
pollution) and  subsequently  emphasizing ex-
panding  pollution control  capital.  In  other
words,  specialization is  to  be preferred over
balanced growth.
   Singleton's evaluationT8  of water pollution
in the Soviet Union found that the USSR has
taken an exploitative development path similar
to what one would  expect in any developing
nation  regardless  of  its  institutions.   This
situation  is a result of planning and adminis-
trative failures with a primary problem being
a lack of incentives to follow leadership prefer-
ences  within  the  Soviet  command  system.
Stretton 7S compared the effectiveness of capi-
talistic and socialistic systems in environmental
management.
  Adar and Griffin's analysis so of situations in
which  uncertainty in the marginal control cost
and  in the marginal pollution  damage  affects
the  optimal  choice  from  among  pollution
charges,  pollution standards,  and the auction-
ing of  pollution  rights determined that uncer-
tainty  in the damage function has no  effect
but that cost uncertainty favors charges when
the damage function is price elastic and favors
standards when  the damage  function is price
inelastic.   Rose's  analysis8l  of using federal
cost sharing to  induce  communities to  adopt
socially optimal  pollution abatement identified
such dilficulties as differences among communi-
ties in  optimal practice, the cost-sharing prac-
tice being based  on total rather than marginal
costs, and  the inherent inflexibility  of federal
funding.  Harford 82 used a calculus of  varia-
tions framework  to delineate  an  optimal time
path for expanding a waste treatment program
and found  that a policy of gradually strength-
ening standards over time can be justified when
the additional cost of adjusting more quickly
to higher standards exceeds the consequences
of  pollution  during  the  intermittent period.
Rose83 explained why a  capital  adjustment
model  was superior to an  acceleration  invest-
ment equation  for  representing  the  cost of
pollution control  equipment  in  input-output
modeling.
  Briller8*  illustrated  discounted   cash  flow
analysis through application to surface mechan-
ical  aerators in a municipal sewage treatment
plant as a  method for minimizing the  cost of
selected  treatment equipment.  The sensitivity
of the  results to 12 independent variables  was
tested  and  compared.   Paulson85  described
how flexibility  to  control construction costs
decreases as a  project progresses  from design
to completion and how costs can be reduced
by drawing contractual arrangements to  assure
that current construction  and  operation prac-
tices  are considered  in  design.    Wolpert8a
documented experiences relating to the siting
of obnoxious public facilities in urban areas in
an  effort to promote more widespread use of
equity criteria in the decision making.
  Leone8T reviewed the impact of environ-
mental control on industry.   Wiley 88  recited
petroleum  industry  experiences of  over one-
quarter of the capital investment  now being
required  for  pollution  control  and  recorn-
 1542  Journal WPCF
                                        2-59

-------
mended  such  policy  changes for  improving
equity as promoting correction  at  the  waste
source and reducing excess capacity in facility
design.  Amberg 89 reported that pollution con-
trol requirements were absorbing  30 percent of
the capital expenditures in the pulp and  paper
industry  and  thereby  draining  capital that
would otherwise be  available for technological
development.   The major need was for change
from a regulatory approach that in  many cases
actually adversely  impacts the overall environ-
ment by blind  adherence to uniform standards
to a system of site-specific controls  to remedy
identified  environmental  problems.   Black et
al.go found that federal water pollution control
requirements will require the typical   carpet
mill to invest up  to a million dollars and in-
crease the  cost of carpet production by  about
5 cents by  1983,  but  that the resulting price
increases  are  probably  too   small  to reduce
sales.  Shlottmann and  Spore 91  showed with
a linear programming model  of the coal  indus-
try that reclamation regulations would reduce
Applachian coal surface mining  by 7 percent
and increase underground mining by 4 percent
but emphasized that the environmental  affects
of underground mining must be  more care-
fully analyzed  before concluding that this is a
wise policy.
  Lee and  Guntermann92  estimated   down-
stream sediment damages for  a wide variety of
farm  practices  within an Illinois  watershed as
the sum of the costs of induced drainage ditch
dredging, reduced reservoir economic life,  loss
of benefits  because of an early end  to reservoir
economic  life,  a sediment component of flood
damage,  and  a  loss  of  recreation benefits.
Guntermann et aZ.9S  found   off-site  sediment
damages to be far greater than on-site produc-
tivity losses, advocated a tax-subsidy incentive
approach to reducing sediment production and
noted  a  lack  in  technical  knowledge  about
sediment  movement as  a major  obstacle  to
establishing an effective program.  Miller and
Gill9* used linear programming  to show how
statewide soil loss standards  in Indiana caused
a  greater percentage and per acre decline in
farm  income  on  small  farms  or  in   rolling
topography than  on  large  farms   or in  flat
topography.  Consideration  of tax incentives
as possibly  more equitable was recommended.
   Pfeiffer and Whittlesey "  analyzed the cost
effectiveness of  taxing  water  use,  reducing
water rights, and  improving  farm water man-
agement  as alternatives for  controlling  the
quality of irrigation return flows and concluded
that  policies  relying  on  higher input costs
 allocate resources mure efficiently while policies
 relying on  input  quotas impose  less  cost on
 agriculture.  Kleinman 9S applied  a linear pro-
 gramming model to estimate farm profit in the
 area served by the Imperial Irrigation District
 as a function of irrigation  water  salinity  con-
 tent.   Erlenkotter and Scherer "7 outlined alter-
 native mathematical formulations  for  optimal
 scheduling  of salinity control projects on the
 Colorado River.
   Sims  and Baumann9S  used questions  ad-
 ministered to 22  state health officials and 98
 consulting engineers to define professional bias
 toward using renovated wastewater and  con-
 cluded that recognition  of bias  was as  im-
 portant as use of expertise in the formulation
 of public policy on environmental issues. From
 telephone interviews of 1 000  Southern  Cali-
 fornia households on  attitudes  toward 13 po-
 tential wastewater reuses ranging from drinking
 to toilet  reuse,  Stone "  found that the public
 favored nonbody contact reuses, favored body
 contact reuses  less strongly, and  was  divided
 in attitude  toward consumptive uses  with the
 primary  negative  factor being psychological
 aversion.  Industrial plant managers and public
 water  officials were less willing than the public
 to accept reuse.   Gates  et al.100  studied the
 reasons why people are unwilling to swim or
 water  ski on the Neches River  (Texas)  and
 related these to measured water quality param-
 eters.   Young101 developed a computerized
 model that compares the  costs  of  solid-set
 irrigation, center-pivot irrigation,  border-strip
 irrigation, ridge-and-furrow irrigation, overland
 flow, and infiltration basins as land application
 of wastewater  technologies.   The center pivot
 system was found least  expensive, and results
 for different kinds of facilities of different  sizes
 were  tabulated.


 REFERENCES
   1. "Report to the Congress."  National Commis-
       sion on Water Quality, Washington, D. C.
       (1976).
1/2. "Water Pollution Control Act  of 1972, En-
       vironmental Impact Assessment."  National
       Commission on Water Quality, Washington,
       D. C. (1975/6).
   3. Allen,  H.  L., et d., "Public Law 92-500—
       Water Quality Analysis and Environmental
       Impact Assessment."  2 volumes,  National
       Commission on Water Quality, 75/100-1,2,
       Washington, D.  C. (1976).
   4. Human Resources Planning Inst., "Water Pol-
       lution Control Act  of  1972, Demographic
       and Quantitative A i.dysis."  National Com-
       mission  on  Water Quality, 75/44, Wash-
       ington, D. C. (1975).
                                       2-60

-------
I
I
I
I
I
 I
 i
 i
 I
 i
 i
 i
  i
  i
  i
   i
   i
   i
   i
 5. Public Research Inst, "Water Pollution Con-
      trol Act of 1972, Economic Impacts,  For-
      eign  Trade."   National  Commission on
      Water Quality, 75/34, Washington, D. C.
      (1976).
 6. Dev. Planning and Res. Asso., "Water Pollu-
      tion  Control Act of 1972, Economic Im-
      pacts,  Dairy Products."  National Com-
      mission on Water Quality,  75/46,  Wash-
      ington, D. C. (1975).
 7. Dev. Planning and Res. Asso., "Water Pollu-
      tion  Control Act of 1972, Economic Im-
      pacts,  Fruits and Vegetables."   National
      Commission on  Water  Quality,   75/45,
      Washington, D. C.  (1975).
 8. Dev. Planning and Res. Asso., "Water Pol-
      lution  Control Act  of 1972, Technologies
      and  Economic  Impacts, The  Feedlot In-
      dustry."   National  Commission on Water
      Quality, 75/47, Washington, D. C.  (1975).
 9. Lusky, R., "A Model of Recycling and  Pol-
      lution Control."   Can.  Joum. Econ., 9, 91
      (1976).
10. Macaulay, H.  H.,  and  Yandle,  T.  B.,  "An
      Economic   Evaluation  of Water  Quality
      Management Systems."  Water Resources
      Res. Inst., Clemson Univ., Clemson, S. C.
      (1975).
11. Marshall, H. E.,  and Ruegg, R. T., "Effi-
      ciency Problems  from  User Fees  in  Mu-
      nicipal  Wastewater Treatment."    Water
      Resources  Butt., 12, 903 ( 1976).
12. McMillan, M.,  "Criteria for Jurisdictional
      Design."   Jour. Environ. Econ. and Man-
      agement, 3, 46 (1976).
13. Tomasini,  L. M., "A  Note on the Fair Di-
      vision of Pollution Rights."  Jour, of Pub-
      lic Economics, 6, 313 ( 1976).
14. Levi, D. R., and Beattie, B. R.,  "Economics
      as an Input in Environmental Law." Land
      Econ., 52,  235  (1976).
15. Williams, F. P.,  and  Rucks,  A.  C.,  "Water
      Pollution Control: Crossroads of a Munici-
      pal  Financial  Dilemma."   Public  Works,
      107,6, 86  (1976).
16. Boyd, D. R., et  al., "Removal vs. Benefits:
      It Can Be Too Costly."  Water 6- Wastes
      Engr., 13,2,42 (1976).
17. Quarles,  J.,  Jr.,  "Cleaning  Up America."
      Houghton  Mifflin Co., Boston ( 1976).
18. Caldwell, L. K.,  et al., "Citizens and the
      Environment: Case  Studies in Popular Ac-
      tion."   Ind.   Univ.  Press,  Bloomington
      (1976).
19. Hammer, E.  R., "Environmental Policy: A
      Sociological Assessment of Abatement Al-
      ternatives."  Gordon   Press  Pubs.,  New
      York (1976).
20. Dimento, J.  F.,  "Managing  Environmental
      Change: A Legal and  Behavioral Perspec-
      tive."  Praeger Pubs., New York ( 1976).
21. Andrews, R.  N.,  "Environmental Policy  and
      Administrative  Change:  Implementation of
                                                  23.
                                                  24.
                                                  £5
                                                  27.


                                                  28.
                                                  30.


                                                  31.



                                                  32.




                                                  33.
                                                  35.
                                                  36
   the  National  Environmental Policy Act."
   Lexington Bks., Lexington, Mass. (1976).
Kneese, A. V., "Economics and the Environ-
   ment."   Penguin  Books,  Inc.,  New  York
   (1976).
Stephens,   J. K.,  "A  Relatively   Optimistic
   Analysis  of Growth  and  Pollution in  a
   Neoclassical Framework."  Jour. Environ.
   Econ. and Management, 3, 85 (1976).
Lipnowski,  I. F.,  "An Input-Output  Anal-
   ysis  of Environmental Preservation."  Jour.
   Environ. Econ.  and Management,  3,  205
   (1976).
Uri, N. D.,  "The Effects of Environmental
   Quality  Standards on  Pricing  Electrical
   Energy."  Environ,  and  Planning A, 8,
   573  (1976).
Eidem, I.,  "Reasons for Having  the  IVL
   Institute  for Water and Air Pollution Con-
   trol  Research."   Svensk  Papperstidning
   (Swed.),79, 5, 143 (1976).
Whipple, W., Jr.,  "Strategy of  Water Pollu-
   tion  Control."   Water Resources Bull, 12,
   1019 (1976).
Whipple, W., Jr.,  and Hufschmidt, M.  M.,
   "Reorientation of Urban-Related Water Re-
   sources Research."  Water Resources Res.,
   12,762 (1976).
Friesema, H. P., and Culhane,  P. J., "Social
   Impacts,  Politics,  and  the Environmental
   Impact   Statement Process."    Nat.   Re-
   sources Jour., 16, 339 (1976).
Wengert,  N., "Citizen  Participation:  Prac-
   tice  in  Search of a Theory."   Nat.  Re-
   sources Jour., 16, 25 (1976).
Tideman, T.  N.,  and Tullock,  G.,  "A New
   and  Superior  Process  for  Making Social
   Choices."  Jour.  Pol.  Econ.,   84,  1145
   (1976).
Lienesch, W. C., and Emison, G. A., "Plan-
   ning  for Implementation  under  Section
   208." Jour. Water Resources  Planning and
   Man. Div., Proc. Amer.  Soc. Civil Engr.,
   102,283  (1976).
Grantham,  G. R., and Bailey, T. E., "Water
   Quality  Planning Strategy."  /our. Water
   Resources Planning and  Man. Div., Proc.
   Amer. Soc. Civil Engr.,  102, 11 (1976).
Bundgaard-Nielsen,  M.,  and Hwang,  C.  L.,
   "A  Review  on Decision Models in Eco-
   nomics of regional Water Quality Manage-
   ment."   Water  Resources  Bull.,  12,  461
   (1976).
McNamara, J, R.,  "An  Optimization  Model
   for Regional Water Quality Management."
   Water Resources Res., 12, 125 (1976).
Bovet,  E. D., "Economic Concepts and Tech-
   niques Pertaining to Water Supply, Water
   Allocation,  and  Water  Quality."   U.  S.
   Army Engr.  Inst.  for  Water  Resources,
   FortBelvoir, Va. (1975).
Rohrlich, G. F.,  "Environmental   Manage-
   ment: Economics and Social  Dimensions."
1544   Journal WPCF
                                         2-61

-------
39.
40.
43.


44.

45.



46.



47.




48.



49.


50.



51.



52.


53.


54.
  Ballinger  Pub.  Co.,  Philadelphia, Penn.
  (1976).
Gum,  R.  L.,  et al, "Quantifying  Societal
  Goals: Development of a Weighting Meth-
  odology."   Water  Resources Res.,  12, 617
  (1976).
Phillips,  K.  J.,  and  DeFilippi,  J.  A.,  "A
  Matrix Approach for  Determining Waste-
  water Management Impacts."  Jour.  Wa-
  ter Poll. Control Fed., 48,  1759  ( 1976).
Hipel, K. W.,  et al,  "Metagame Theory and
  Its Applications to Water Resources."  Wa-
  ter Resources Res.,  12, 331 ( 1976).
Hipel, K. W., et al, "Political Resolution  of
  Environmental Conflicts."  Water Resources
  Bull, 12,813 (1976).
Ragade,  R.  K., et  al.,  "Metarationality  in
  Benefit-Cost Analyses."   Water Resources
  Res., 12, 1069 (1976).
Van Praag, B. M. S., and Linthorst, J., "Mu-
  nicipal Welfare Functions."   Reg.  Science
  ir Urban Econ, (Neth.), 6, 51 (1976).
Trigg, L. ]., et al, "Anti-Pollution Behavior."
  Environ, and Behavior, 8, 307 ( 1976 ) .
Brill, E. D., Jr., et al, "Equity Measures for
  Exploring Water Quality  Management Al-
  ternatives."   Water Resources  Res.,   12,
  845 (1976).
Brumm, H. J., and Dick, D.  T., "Federal En-
  vironmental Policy and   R&D  on  Water
  Pollution Abatement."  Amer. Econ. Rev.,
  66,2,448 (1976).
Herzog, H.  W., Jr., "Economic  Efficiency
  and Equity in Water Quality Control Efflu-
  ent Taxes and Information Requirements."
  Jour. Environ. Econ. and  Management,  2,
  170 (1976).
Dick,  D. T.,  "The  Voluntary  Approach  to
  Externality  Problems:  A Survey  of the
  Critics."   Jour. Environ.  Econ. and Man-
  agement, 2,  185 ( 1976).
Mathur, V. K., "Spatial Economic Theory  of
  Pollution  Control."  Jour. Environ. Econ.
  and Management, 3, 16 ( 1976).
Bundgaard-Nielsen, M.,  "A Note on the Use
  of  Economic  Incentives   in Water Pollu-
  tion Abatement."  Water Resources Bull,
  12,755(1976).
DeWees, D.  N.,  and Sims,  W.  A.,  "The
  Symmetry of  Effluent Charges  and Sub-
  sidies for Pollution Control."   Can. Jour,
  Econ., 9, 323 (1976).
Smith, V. K.,  "A  Note  on  Effluent Charges
  and Market  Structure."   Jour.  Environ.
  Econ. and Management, 2, 309  ( 1976),
Orr,  L., "Incentive  for  Innovation  as the
  Basis for Effluent Charge Strategy."  Amer.
  Econ. Rev., 66, 2, 441 ( 1976).
Holtermann, S.,  "Alternative Tax  Systems  to
  Correct for  Externalities, and the  Effi-
  ciency of Paying  Compensation."  Eco-
  nomics, 43,  1 (1976).
   55.  Mulkey, D., and Stepp, J., "A Review of
         Sewer Charge Experience in South Caro-
         lina."  Water  Resources Res. Inst.,  Clem-
         son Univ., Clemson, S. C. (1975).
   56.  Ehler,  C.  N.,  et al,  "Development  of  Re-
         siduals Management Strategies."  Environ.
         Protection Agency, 600/1-76-01/B, Wash-
         ington, D. C. (1976).
   57.  Campbell, H.  F.,  "On  the Income  Distri-
         butional Effects of Environmental Manage-
         ment Policies." Water Resources Res., 12,
         1077 (1976).
   58.  Keith, J.  E., et  al, "An Empirical  Analysis
         of  Predictors of Income Distribution  Ef-
         fects of Water Quality Controls."  PRRAE-
         015, Utah Water  Res.  Lab.,  Utah State
         Univ., Logan, Utah (1976).
   59.  Edwards, W. F., and Langham, M.  R., "Pub-
         lic Welfare in Relation to Alternative Pesti-
         cide Policies."  Jour.  Environ. Econ.  and
         Management, 2, 295 (1976).
   60.  Asch,  P., and  Seneca, J. J., "Monopoly  and
         External Costs: An Application of Second-
         Best Theory to the Automobile Industry."
         Jour. Environ. Econ. and Management, 3
         69 (1976).
   61.  Cowing,  T. G.,  "The  Environmental  Im-
         plications 'if  Monopoly Regulation: A Pro-
         cess  Analysis  Approach."  Jour. Environ.
         Econ. and Management, 2, 207 (1976).
   62.  Peskin,  H.  M.,  "A  National  Accounting
         Framework  for  Environmental  Assets."
         Jour. Environ. Econ. and Management, 2,
         255 (1976).
   63.  Sandier, T., and Smith, V. K., "Intertemporal
         and  Intergenerational  Pareto  Efficiency."
         Jour. Envu^n. Econ. and Management 2
         151 (1976).
   64.  White, R. D..  "The Anatomy  of Nonmarket
         Failure: An  Examination of Environmental
         Policies."  Amer.  Econ. Rev.,  66,  2,  454
         (1976).
f 65.  Dworsky, L. B., et al.,  "Workshop Report:
         Integrating Water Quality and Water  and
         Land Resources Planning."   Univ. Council
         on Water Resources and the Engr. Founda-
         tion,  Cornell  Univ.,  Ithaca,  New  York
         (1976).
   66.  Bammi, D., et  al, "Urban Planning to Mini-
         mize  Environmental  Impact."   Environ.
         and Planning A, 8, 245 (1976).
   67.  Black, Crow, and Eidsness, Inc., "Water Pol-
         lution Abatement Technology:  Capabilities
         and Costs, Urban Runoff." National Com-
         mission  on Water  Quality,  75/14, Wash-
         ington, D. C. (1975).
   68.  Walter, I., Ed., "Studies in International  En-
         vironmental  Economics."  John  Wiley  &
         Sons, New York (1976).
   69.  Pethig, R., "Pollution, Welfare,  and Environ-
         mental Policy  in the Theory of Compara-
         tive Advantage." Jour. Environ. Econ. and
         Management, 2, 160 (1976).
                                       2-62

-------
  I
  I
  1
 I
 i
 i
 I
 i
 i
 i
 i
 i
 i
 i
 i
 i
 i
i
i
Literature Review
 70. Dombusch, D. M., et al, "Benefits from Wa-
       ter Pollution Abatement, Property Values."
       Dombusch and Co., San Francisco (1975).
 71. Klee, A.  ] ,  "Models for Evaluation of Haz-
       ardous Wastes." Jour. Environ. Div., Proc.
       Amer.  Soc. Civil Engr., 102,  111  (1976).
 72. Teniere-Buchot, P. F., "The Role of the Pub-
       lic  in  Water  Management  Decisions  in
       France."    Nat.  Resources  jour., 16,  159
       (1976).
 73. Seifert, K.,  and Lyons,  T.  C., "Water Qual-
       ity Law in Federal Republic of Germany."
       Jour. Water Resources Planning and Man.
       Div.,  Proc. Amer. Soc.  Civil Engr.,  102,
       23 (1976).
 74. Johnson,  R.  W.,  and  Brown, G. M.,  Jr.,
       "Cleaning  Up  Europe's Waters: Econom-
       ics, Management, Policies."  Praeger Publ.,
       New York (1976).
 75. Laburn, R.  J., "Some Aspects of Water Man-
       agement  in the P.W.V.  Metropolitan  Re-
       gion."   Water  Resources   Bull.,  12,  65
       (1976).
 76. Onokerhoraye, A. G., "Urban  Environmental
       Problems and Planning Strategies in Tropi-
       cal  Africa:  The  Example  of Nigeria."
       The  Annals  of Reg.  Science,   10, 2,  24
       (1976).
 77. Gruver,  G.  W., "Optimal Investment  in Pol-
       lution  Control  Capital in  a  Neoclassical
       Growth Context."  Jour. Environ. Econ.
       and Management,  3, 165 (1976).
 78. Singleton, F., Ed.,  "Environmental  Misuse
       in the  Soviet Union."   Praeger Pubs.,  New
       York (1976).
 79. Stretton,  H.,  "Capitalism,  Socialism, and the
       Environment."   Cambridge  Univ.   Press,
       Gr. Britain (1976).
 80. Adar, Z., and Griffin, J.  M., "Uncertainty and
       the Choice of  Pollution Control  Instru-
       ments."  Jour.  Environ. Econ.  and Man-
       agement, 3, 178 (1976).
 81. Rose,  M., "A Note on Cost Sharing  of Mu-
       nicipal  Wastewater   Pollution  Abatement
       Projects."   Land Econ., 52,  554 (1976).
 82. Harford,  ].  D., "Adjustment  Costs and Op-
       timal  Waste  Treatment."   Jour. Environ.
       Econ. and Management, 3, 215 (1976).
 83. Rose, A., "A Note on the Investment Equa-
       tions in Some Recent Environmental-Man-
       agement  Models."  Environ, and Planning
       A, 8,477 (1976).
 84. Brillor, R.,  "Discounted Cash  Flow Analysis
       to  Select  Equipment."   Jour.  Environ.
       Div.,  Proc. Amer.  Soc.  Civil Engr.,  102,
       595 (1976).
 85. Paulson,  B.  C.,  Jr., "Designing  to  Reduce
       Construction Costs."    Jour. Construction
       Div.,  Proc. Amer. Soc.  Civil Engr.,  102,
       587 (1976).
 86. Wolpert, J., "RegresSi.e  Siting  of  Public
       Facilities."  Nat. Resources Jour., 16, 103
       (1976).
 87.  Leone,  R. A., "Environmental Controls:  The
       Impact  on Industries."  Lexington  Bks.,
       Lexington, Mass. (1976).
 88.  Wiley, M. A., "Water Pollution Control, Mid-
       course  Correction."   Chemtech, 6, 2, 134
       (1976).
 89.  Amberg,  H. R.,  "Environmental and  Social
       Factors  in  the Paper  Industry."  Tappi,
       59,4,68 (1976).
 90.  Black, B., et al., "Cost of Water Pollution
       in  the  Carpet  Industry."  Amer.  Dyestuff
       Reporter, 65, 6, 16 (1976).
 91.  Schlottmann, A., and Spore, R. L., "Economic
       Impacts  of  Surface Mine  Reclamation."
       Land Econ., 52, 265 (1976).
 92.  Lee,  M. T., and Guntennann, K. L., "A Pro-
       cedure  for Estimating  Off-Site  Sediment
       Drainage Costs and an  Empirical  Test."
       Water  Resources Bull.,  12,  561 (1976).
 93.  Guntermann,  K.  L., et al., "The Economics
       of  Off-Site  Erosion." The Annals o/  Reg.
       Science, 10,3,  117 (1976).
 94.  Miller,  W. L., and Gill, J. H., "Equity Con-
       siderations  in  Controlling  Nonpoint  Pol-
       lution from Agricultural Sources."  Water
       Resources Bull., 12, 253 (1976).
 95.  Pfeiffer, G. H., and Whittlesey,  N. K., "Eco-
       nomic Costs of Controlling Water Quality
       through Management of  Irrigation Return
       Flows."  Washington Water Research  Ctr.,
       Washington State Univ.,  Pullman (1976).
 96.  Kleinman, A. P., "Evaluation of Economic
       Impacts of Salinity  on  Agricultural  Water
       Users  in the Lower Colorado River Basin."
       In  "Colorado  River Basin Modeling Stud-
       ies."   C.  G.  Clyde, et  al. [Eds.],  Utah
       State Univ., Logan,  Utah (1976).
 97.  Erlenkotttr,  D.,  and  Scherer,  C.  R.,  "In-
       vestment Planning  for Colorado River Sa-
       linity Control."  In  "Colorado River Basin
       Modeling  Studies."   C.  G. Clyde,  et al.
       [Eds.],  Utah  State  Univ.,  Logan,  Utah
       (1976).
 98.  Sims, J. H., and  Baumann, D. D., "Profes-
       sional  Bias  and  Water  Reuse."   Econ.
       Geography, 52, 1 (1976).
 99.  Stone, R., "Water Reclamation:  Technology
       and  Public Acceptance."   Jour.  Environ.
       Div.,  Proc. Amer.  Soc. Civil  Engr.,  102,
       581 (1976).
100.  Gates, D. G., et al., "Effects of Water Qual-
       ity on the Recreational Use  of  Water  in
       South East Texas."  Water Resources Inst.,
       Univ. of Texas, Austin, Texas (1976).
101.  Young,  C.  E., "The  Cost of Land  Applica-
       tion  of Wastewater: A  Simulation Anal-
       ysis."   Econ. Research  Serv., Tech.  Bull.
       No. 1555, Washington,  D. C. (1976).   '
1546   Journal WPCF
                                       2-63

-------
(Economics

J.  C. Hite,  Clemson University, S. C.

L. D. James
Utah Water  Resources Laboratory,  Logan

   During 1978  there were no  new  trends in
the  literature related  to  water quality eco-
nomics.  For  more than  a decade,  the main-
stream of this literature has focused on poten-
tial  use  of  effluent  charges or  other  similar
pseudomarket devices as an alternative to stan-
dards and  regulations.   Of  the 39  articles,
reports, monographs, and texts reviewed  here-
in, 10 concentrated  almost exclusively  on the
use of such market devices, while several others
subsumed  their  existence.  Such  work has
been especially attractive to theoretical econo-
mists, probably because jt has been  relatively
easy to refine  the theory to explicitly allow for
various types  of effluent charges, and to do so
without becoming involved in time-consuming,
often frustrating, data-collection chores.   En-
gineers  and public agency administrators are
often critical  of this work, however, contend-
ing  that theoreticians  fail to  account  for  a
myriad of real-world, practical problems.  Nev-
ertheless,  while  much   of this  work  is not
directly applicable to specific management and
policy problems,  a Irage amount of  the litera-
ture  dealing with use of effluent charges has
helped to clarify issues  and has opened new
vistas for policy.
   There  were a number  of articles in  1978
that  advanced understanding of how effluent -
charges might be used effectively.  Miedema l
used a  partial-equilibrium,  competitive-firm
model to test the effects  of various types of
charges on materials balance accounts. Magat -
compared  unit  effluent  charges and effluent
standards to determine potential effects of each
in inducing technological change and was un-
able to identify any qualitative  differences in
the  R&D expenditures of firms  under the two
diUeiem M i.,-iii».',.   h: concluded,  liu\\ir\or,
that per uiut  <. ;.luenr  iLa^cs  would have to
be  continually  increased to  halt a  growth m
effluents if one assumes advancing technology.
Moffit  tit ul.J  developed  a  methodology for
calculating eiiicii.-nt  diluent  taxes  or charges
and demonstrated it;; practicality  by applying
it  to daily pollution problems  in California's
Santa Ana Uivi r liaMn.  Many of  the  critics
of ellluuit rli.irf/.i-s li.n/c focused their criticisms
on  the pi.ictir.il piobk.'nis of  the charges, 'j lie
work by Moiiit and his colleagues is especially
significant, thriefoio, because  it showed that
a simple, eliiueiit i:illuent chaige scheme could
be  developed from the same data  base needed
to compute uniform, least-cost emissions stan-
dards.   Harford '  also replied to the critics of
effluent charges in a paper examining the be-
havior  of profit-maximizing  firm  wheie both
pollution  standards  and   effluent   taxes  or
charges  are  not  perfectly  enforceable.  He
demonstrated that increasing the level of pen-
alties for  violating  standards  would  reduce
pollution but that stricter  enforcement  would
not necessarily achieve that end.   Increasing
effluent taxes or charges will reduce  pollution.
but will also cause firms to use more resources
in evasion  of the effluent tax.  Since the mar-
ginal cost of  effluent  treatment rises with
higher and higher levels of pollutant removal
the potential rewaids of evasion also rise, and
thus,  the marginal cost of  enforcement: rises
as  the control  standards  become more strin-
gent.  The marginal social  damages of  addi-
tional  pollution must  be  sufficient   to  justify
not only the marginal costs of physical removal
but  also  the  marginal  cost of enforcement.
Caitee and Williams ° also examined enforce-
ment problems, focusing specifically  on  pollu-
tion control in  coastal  areas
  Some  new  twists  on  the use  of effluent
charges were  introduced in the  literature  in
1978.  Gates and Strassmann "  examined pos-
sible application  of  effluent  charges  to  public
sector acti\ ities and  showed, in certain plausi-
ble cases,  that such  charges can induce sig-
nificant reduction  in pollution.  Unger 7 inter-
jected  spatial considerations  into the analysis,
taking  specific account of the direction of flow
of a stream and the juxtaposition  of upstream
and downstream  users of water.  His analysis
provided a basis  for determining optimal site-
specific  discharges  and the pricing scheme
necessary to  achieve that optimum.  Huszar
and Sabey"8  examined how quality levels  in
the return flow from  irrigation might be im-
proved  by a pricing  scheme.  Trock  et a/.'
1098  Journal VVPCF, Vol. 51, No. 6
                                        2-64

-------
   I
   I
   1
   I
   1
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
I
t iv> examined  the phvsicv.l.  e'-.>n«mi< .  '<":al
ilid social measures that mmht I1"1 us,.'d to deal
,vith lalm'tv  problems resulting  from  the  r°.-
tuui flow  from irrigation and recommended,
iniMig other measures, \vater trading among
users   All of  these studies  have considerable
potential  in the  insights  they provide thi'M?
charged \vith  refining  water pollution  control
policy.
  Yet  \vhile policy makers  are  beginning to
uarm  to the idea  ot effluent charges and other
market mechanisms as tools  that  ha\e prac-
tical use,  the  debate  oxer  policv  continues.
Portney l" edited  a volume  in which  five dis-
tinguished economists reviewed the social and
institutional  factors causing  the U  S  to favor
direct  regulations  over market  mechanisms that
use reward  and  penaltv  incentives  and  dis-
incentives.   The concensus  ^vas that the rogu-
latorv  approach  has   'and  is'   straining  the
nation's  ability to  pursue  its economic  and
environmental  goals and  that a  shift  tov. ard
greater use of  charges  and so  forth, is needed.
Ricketts and Webb,11 however, argued that, in
most practical  circumstances, very complicated
tax i or  charge)  structures  would  be  needed
to achieve  environmental goals  at least  cost.
Dav,1- explored  a  new approach  to  policv,
emphasizing flexibility rather than efficiency
\rguing that economists and  other social sci-
entists are incapable of accurately predicting
future conditions  he stated that they should
guide  policy makers so as  to make them better
able to deal  with  "surprises."  The  precise im-
plications  of  his  argument  relative  to  the
debate over effluent charges is a matter likely
to attract considerable  attention in  the future.
Indeed,  an  article  by  Storev and WalkerI3
explored  traditional versus  "adaptive"  models
for setting standards and  emphasized  the role
of uncertainty  in making policy decisions.
   As in most years, a  large  part  of the litera-
ture of water quality econotrics in  1978 dealt
vv'th development or  application of  planning
models.   Baker u  developed a model for plan-
ing and  locating on-site waste  disposal sys-
tems,  while Brinkley   and  Hanemann 15  con-
tributed to "the literature of  recreational  re-
source planning.  Muller's l(i econometric study
°f the Canadian  pulp  and  paper industry  in-
'Jicated that the costs of pollution control  were
'-inhkely  to  adversely  affect that industry's
economic performance.  In  what was  possibly
°'ic of the more interesting papers of the year,
"fookshire l~ bridged the gap between regional
Planning  and  the  theoretical discussions  of
effluent charges or subsidies for pollution con-
tiol   He noted that proposed uses of charges,
taxes, and subsidies are all piemised  on exist-
ing institutional •)tnicfiires such as schools and
road, and do  not  address  alteration  of those
structures   Biookshirc argued that alterations
,n  the   institutional  structure  of  a  region
through  exogenous investments are also valid
\vavs to  achieve  readjustments  needed  to
achie\ e \\ ater qualitv  and other environmental
goals  Peeie ct rt/.;s  also gave attention to in-
stitutional factors and  their effect on the dis-
tnbution  of  benefits  and  costs  in particular
communities.   In taking  into account possible
uses  of  migration  data  to  draw  inferences
about the values of  environmental amenities,
Brookslme bnefk explored a topic developed
in more  depth  bv  Sigmon.'J   Sigmon used
the ^ell-known  Tiebout  Model to develop  a
econometric  procedure  tor estimating  trade-
otfs between environmental amenities and in-
come concluding that while serious technical
pioblcms must  be overcome in the econometric
procedures,  such an approach has promise for
estimating the monetary value of environmental
improvements.
  The literature  showed  continued  progress
in  modeling   economic-ecologic  interfaces.
O'Havre and Mace-0  made use of  modified
input-output anahsis  to  examine the  spatial
distribution   of  pollutants  from  nonpoint  as
\vell as  point sources and applied their  model
to an evaluation of the economic-ecologic ef-
fects ot various forest management alternatives.
Stacey  and  Flmn J1  also  used  input-output
techniques to estimate environmental impacts
of new  products developed by specific  indus-
tries.   Honey and Hogg -- explored use  of  a
cultural-ecological model in social impact as-
sessment with  specific application to the tem-
poral and spatial  effects of lake restoration
programs.   Griffith -"J  recommended  use of  a
Lorenx,  curve to show the  spatial inequalities
arising from project implementation and made
a start  toward  fusing  social welfare analysis
and economic analysis in  assessment methodol-
ogy.  WidstrandC4  edited  a. study  from the
Scandinavian Institute  of African Studies that
also  emphasized  the  need  for better  under-
standing of  institutional obstacles to  improved
water quality  planning,  particularly in Third
World countries.   Finally, Willeke:5 studied
the equity of  financial arrangements used  in
paying for municipal water  quality control pro-
grams and  concluded  that  some  institutional
practices, such  as  rate structures which sub-
sidize new  residents,  were significant  causes
of inequity.
                                                                           June 1979  1099
                                          2-65
                                                                                                                            <§

-------
  In  1978 there was gro\ving  public  conearn
about  the costs of  environmental protection
measures  and their effect on inflation.  Segal
and Drieling •6  surveyed expenditures  011 pol-
lution  abatement and control  in  the  U. S. in
the period from 1972 to 1976 and found that
expenditures on water  pollution  control and
abatement increased at an annual rate of about
15%in  the 4-year period.  The  engineering
firm of Dames and Moore prepared three stud-
ies for EPA: a  study of construction  costs of
536 treatment plants,-7 a study of costs of 455
conveyance facilities,28 and  a  study of opera-
tions  and maintenance costs of 348 treatment
plants and 155  sewer collection systems.29  A
similar  study from Great Britain3" examined
costs  of  constructions for water  supply and
wastewater disposal  facilities  and  used  the
results to develop  a  model for  cost estimation
in national and regional  planning.  Clark and
English 31 focused  on the costs of using reno-
vated  waste  water to supplement water sup-
plies   and  found  that  the least  expensive
method would increase the total cost of waters
by  about 25%.  Vaughan 3J concentrated  on
estimating costs of  pollution  control  at  the
plant level, using  process analysis and a  de-
tailed  linear programming model, while Brill
and  Nakamura  33   demonstrated the use of a
branch and bound procedure to  generate  al-
ternative   planning  schemes   in   wastewater
treatment plant design.  A  study of the eco-
nomics of chloroform removal from  drinking
water  by Cumberland and Choi3* questioned
the cost effectiveness of making major  changes
in  treatment   of  drinking  water  supplies.
Young's  study  of  the cost of land application
of wastewater,35 however, found  center-pivot
irrigation of municipal waste to be quite cost-
effective for  small  communities.
   In  closing, a note should be made of several
general studies  of  significance.   A monograph
by  Ayres 3B  examined the use of large-scale,
materials-balance   models   in   environmental
planning.  N'ijkamp J: published  a major new
text  in environmental economics  that will  be
useful to advanced students.  Goodall et a/.38
analyzed  the fiscal  practices of California water
districts and Dale J9  surveyed  the impact of
Proposition  13  on operations  of  wastewater
treatment facilities in California.

REFERENCES
  \. Miedema, A. K., "Short-Run Output and Fac-
      tor  Demand Eft'ects  of a Residuals  Charge."
      Land Econ.,  54, 228 (1978).
  2. Magat, W.  A.,  "Pollution Control and Tech-
      nological Advance:  A Dynamic Model of the
      Finn."  /i>ur.  Environ. Econ. and  A/gt., 5
      1 (1978).
 3.  Morfit, L. ]., ct al., "A 'Putty-Clay' Approach
      to Aggregation of Pioduction/Polmtion Pos-
      sibilities:  An  Application  in Dairy  Waj.te
      Control."   Amer. Jour. ,\^r.  Econ., GO,  452
      (1978).
 4.  Harford, }.  D ,  "Finn  Behavior  Under  Im-
      perfectly  Enforceable  Pollution Standards
      and Taxes." Jour, Environ. Econ. and Mgt,
      5,26 (1978).
 5.  Cartee,  C.  P., and Williams,  D.  C.,  Jr.,  "A
      Study of Coastal Pollution and  Agency  In-
      terface."  Water Resources  Bull, 14, 1167
      (1978).
 6.  Dates, W.  E., and Strassmann, D.  L., "The
      Use of Effluent Fees to Regulate Public Sec-
      tor Sources of  Pollution."   Jour.  Environ,
      Econ. and Ugt, 5, 283 ( 1978).
 7.  Unger,  K., "Locutional  Pricing of an Environ-
      mental  Input."  jour.  Environ. Econ.  and
      Met., 5, 207 (1978).
 8.  Huszar, P.  C.. and Sabey, M.  B.,  "Improving
      Irrigation  Return Flow Quality with a Water
      Rental Market."  Water Resources Bull,  14,
      978 (1978).
 9.  Trock, W. L., et al., "Socio-Economic and  In-
      stitutional Factors in  Irrigation Return Flow
      Quality Control."  EPA-600/2-78-174-1/4,
      Robert S.  Kerr Environmental Research Lab-
      oratory, Ada, Okla. (1978).
10.  "Current Issues in U. S. Environmental Policy."
      Portney,  P. R.  [Ed.],  The  Johns  Hopkins
      Univ. Press, Baltimore, Md. (1978).
11.  Ricketts, M.. and Webb,  M. G., "Pricing  and
      Standards  in  the  Control  of   Pollution."
      Scand. Jour. Econ., 80, 53 (1978).
12.  Day,  Richard H., "Adaptive Economics  and
      Natural  Resources  Policy."  Amer.  Jour.
      Afjrt. Econ , 60. 276 ( 1978).
U.  Storey,  D. ]., and Walker, M., "Water Pollu-
      tion  Control  Theory—An  Economic Tax-
      onomy "    jour.  Environ.   \lgt.,  7,  205
      ( 1978).
11  Baker, F G., "A  Model  for Planning and Loca-
      tion of On-Site Waste  Disposal Systems."
      Water Resources Bull,  14, 144 (1978).
15.  Bnnkley, C. S., and Hanemann, W.  M., "The
      Recreation Benefits of Water Quality  Im-
      provement:  \nalysis of  Day Trips  in  an
      Urban Setting" 'EPS-600/5-78-010,  Wash-
      ington, D.  C. (1978).
16.  Muller,  R.  A., "Econometric  Analysis of  En-
      vironmental Policy: Estimation  of  a  Model
      of the Canadian Pulp and Paper Industry."
      Can.  Jour. Econ., 11, 263 ( 1978).
17.  Brookshire, D. S., "A Macroeconomic Analysis
      of  Regional  Environmental  Modeling  and
      Planning."  Jour. Environ. Econ. and Afgt.,
      5, 268 (1978).
18.  Peele,  E.,  ct al.,  "Social Impact Analyses."
      Social Impact Aists.smt'«t, 28, 3  ( 1979).
 1100   Journal WPCF,  Vol.  51,  No. 6
                                        2-66

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
i
i
i
20
22
26
19.  Sicrnon,  B , "Preferences  for Lnoadon-Deprn-
      dent Goods  as  Revealed  !iv  Migration."
      Paper  presented  at  Southern   Regional
      Science  Assoc.  meetings,  Richmond,   Va
      (April 1978).
    O'Hayre,  A. P., and  Mace, A.  C.,  "Hydro-
      nomic Analysis: A Method of Regional Anal-
      ysis of Economic  and Water Resources Rela-
      tionships."   Jour.  Environ.  Mat,  ~1,   125
      (1978).
    Stacy, G. S., and Flinn,  J.  E., "Development of
      an Economics-Based  Methodology  for  Pro-
      jection Future Pollution  Problems."  EPA-
      600/5-78-011, Washington, D. C. (1978)
    Honey, W. D., and Hogg, T. C., "A  Rescaich
      Strategy for Social  Assessment of Lake  Res-
      toration Programs "  EPA-600/5-78-Q04   En-
      vironmental Research Laboratory, Corvallis,
      Oreg  (1978).
23.  Griffith,  C., "A  Welfare  Approach  to Social
      Impact Assessment. '  Social  Impact Assess-
      ment, 34, 9 ( 1978).
24.  "The Social and Ecological Effects  of Water
      Development   in   Developing  Countries "
      Widstrand.  C. G.  [Ed.],  Pergamon Press,
      Oxford, U. K.  (1978).
25.  Willeke, G, E., "Assessing the Social Effects of
      Water Quality Management Programs."  En-
      vironmental Resources Center,  Rept  03-78,
      Georgia Inst. of Technology, Atlanta ( 1978).
    Segal, F. W., and  Drieling, F.  J  "Pollution
      Abatement and Control  Expenditures, 1972-
      76."  Sure,  of Current BUT., 58, 12 (Feb-
      ruary 1978).
27.  "Construction Costs for  Municipal Wastewater
      Treatment  Plants:  197,3-1977."  Dames &
      Moore,   EPA-430/9-77-013,    Washington,
      D. C. (1978).
28.  "Construction Costs for  Municipal Wastewater
      Conveyance Systems: 1973-1977."   Dames
      &  Moore, EPA-430/9-77-014,  Washington,
      D. C. (1978).
29.  "Analysis of Operations and Maintenance Costs
      for Municipal  Wastewater Treatment  Sys-
      tems." EPS-430/9-77-015, Dames & Moore,
      Washington, D. C. (1978).
30.  "Cost Information for Water Supply and Sew-
      age  Disposal?'   Water  Research   Centre,
      Medmanham Laboratory,  Tech. Report  TR
      Sljdarlow, Bucks, U. K. (1977).
    Clark, R. A., and English, J. N., "Cost Studies
      for Renovated Wastewater."   Jour,  Water
      Poll. Control Fed., 50, 688 (1978).
    Vaughan, W. J.,  "Process Analysis for Environ-
      mental Quality Management Modeling: Gen-
      eral  Considerations  and  a  Practical  Ex-
      ample."  Jour. Environ. 1/gt., 7, 101 (1978).
    Brill, E. D., Jr., and Nakamtira, M., "A Branch
      and Bound Method for Use in Planning  Re-
      gional  Wastewater  Treatment  Facilities,"
      Water Resources Res., 14,  109 (1978).
    Cumberland, J. H.,  and Choi, K.. "Economic
      Analysis of Chloroform Removal from Drink-
31
32
33
                                                 36.
                                                  39
  ins;  W.itcr  '   Wif'T  Rfionrces  ?•••<> irch
  Center. Tech  Kept.  49. Univ. of Maryland,
  ColK«.. Park i 1978).
Young,  C.  E.,  "Land  Application  of  Waste-
  water  A Cost Analysis."   U.  S. Dept. of
   \gnc-iilrure.  Economics, Statistics, ind  Co-
  
-------
     Economics
     and the Envaronmarr
     Allen V. Kneese
                             Table of Contents

Tlie Delaware Study                           151
The Model                                 153
Analysis of Objectives                         \ 54
Benefits of Improved  Water Quality                159
Effluent Charges on the Delaware Estuary            162
Flintier Comments on the Effluent Charge Approach      166
Stochastic Hydrology                         168
The Potomac Study                           170
The Basin and Its Problems                      171
Searching for Additional Alternatives                175
Stochastic Aspects                            178
Conclusions from the  Potomac Study                180
Other Reseat ch and Experiences                   181
The Trent Study     ,                        183
The Westernport Bay Land-Use Model              187
Concluding Comment            '              193
         Penguin Books
                  2-68

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 i
 I
 I
 i
 i
 i
i
i
i
 Chapter 7
 Economic Studies of Water-Quality
 Management in Particular  Basins
 Chapter 6 has laid the methodological groundwork for a con-
 sideration of some actual case studies in  this chapter. The
 first of them is regarded by many as  the  'classic' economic
 water-quality management study.  It was  conducted  in  the
 1960s by a Federal Government Agency in the United States
 and focused on the Delaware estuary region. The basic model
 it developed  has  found many other applications in both
 aqueous  and  atmospheric  environments.  The  other  case
 studies with different geographical setting, somewhat different
 methodologies, and addressing different aspects of  water-
 quality problems are also reviewed. While all of  them made
 significant contributions, a common deficiency of all of these
 studies is that they do not incorporate  the  possibility of
 land-use  controls  in an integral manner. In view of this an
 ongoing  study which attempts to remedy this deficiency is
 reviewed at the end of the chapter.

 The Delaware Study

 The Delaware river basin, though small by the standards of
 the great American river basins and draining an area of only
 12,765 square miles, holds a population of over  six million.
 Portions of  the basin,  especially the  Lehigh sub-basin and
 the Delaware estuary  area,  are  among  the most  highly
 industrialized and densely populated regions in the world, and
 it is in these areas that  the main water-quality problems are
" encountered.1 The Delaware estuary, an eighty-six-mile reach
                                                     151
                          2-69

-------
Economics and the Environment

of the Delaware river from Trenton, New Jersey, to Listen
Point, Delaware (see Map  1), is most important in terms of
the quantity of water impacted, the area involved, the extent
of industrial activity, and the number of people affected.
  Despite early industrial and municipal development in the
basin, water-quality problems  were neglected until the last
few  decades. The Interstate Commission on the Delaware
River Basin (INCODEL) was formed in 1936, and under its
auspices the states in the basin signed a reciprocal agreement
on water-quality  control.  This  provided  the legal basis for
construction of treatment plants by municipalities after the
Second World War. The standards of treatment achieved were
not particularly high  (on  the average  not much more than
removal of the grosser  solids), and the residual waste load
from the  plants, together with industrial  discharges,  con-
tinued to place very heavy oxygen demands on the estuary.
Especially during the warm summer months, DO fell, and
Still falls, to low levels or becomes exhausted in a few portions
of  the reach  of the  estuary  from  Philadelphia  to the
Pennsylvania-Delaware state line.
  There are many water-quality characteristics  which affect
the value of the various  services of a watercourse. As we saw
in Chapter 2, and at the end of the previous chapter, one of the
most central is DO, which is affected by meteorological and
hydrological variables and by the discharge of organic wastes.
DO is also something of a  surrogate measure for  other
quality characteristics.  The  peiformance  of waste  water
treatment plants is usually  measured in terms of their ability
to remove BOD from waste waters. Thus my discussion of the
analysis of the Delaware estuary is focused primarily (but not
exclusively) on oxygen conditions.
  In  1957-8, at the request of the Corps of Engineers (the
federal  agency responsible for  developing  'comprehensive'
plans in the river basins of the eastern United States), the
U.S.  Public Health  Service (which  at that time was the
responsible federal agency in regard to water pollution - now
it is  the  Federal Water  Quality  Administration) made  a

152
                     2-70

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
        Economic Studies of Water-Quality Management

preliminary study of water quality in the Delaware estuary.
The data it produced regarding the quality of the estuary led
state and interstate agencies, concerned with water quality, to
request a comprehensive study of the estuary under  the
provisions of the Federal Water Pollution  Control  Act. The
study was begun in 1961, and in the summer of 1966 a report
was issued by the Federal Water Pollution Control Admini-
stration - Delaware Estuary Comprehensive Study: Preliminary
Report and Findings.2 The study made an  effort to measure
external costs as well as costs of control associated with
various policy alternatives. One of its main contributions was
to  link the  model  of waste degradation  and reaeration
(Streeter-Phelps) for multiple  points of discharge, which I
described briefly at the end of the last chapter, to an economic
optimization model.

The Model

Assume that a watercourse consists of n homogenous segments
(thirty segments were used in the Delaware estuary study) and
c( represents  the improvement in water quality required to
meet a DO target in segment /.  The target vector c of m
elements can  be obtained by changes of inputs to the water-
course from combinations of the n segments. Define another
vector x = (x,, xh..., xn) in which the values of x refer to
the volume of waste discharges in  each of the segments. In a
feasible solution, these values represent the waste discharges
at the  various points which meet the target vector c. This
vector generates DO changes through the mechanism of the
constant  coefficients  of the linear transfer  function system
already described at the end of the last chapter: ati = DO
improvement   in  segment /  per unit reduction of  xlt
i= 1,..., m;y = !,...,«; and,  of course x, > 0.
  If we let A  be the (m by n) matrix of transfer coefficients,
then Ax is the vector of DO changes corresponding to x.
  Now, recalling that c is the vector of target improvements,
we have two restrictions on x, namely, Ax ^ c and x ^. 0.
                                                     153
                         2-71

-------
Economics and the Environment

The reader will have noticed that mathematically these ar
sets of linear  constraints  exactly analogous to those m the
industrial production problem I used as an example in the
previous chapter.  All  we need is an objective function to
complete the problem.  Let d be a row vector where d, = un;t
cost of x,,j = 1,... ,n. Notice that this assumes linear cost
functions.3 We can  now  write the problem as a  standard
linear program,
                 minimum value of dx
                         such that Ax > c
                              and  x > 0
  Of course, the transfer coefficients a(,, as already explained,
relate to a steady state of  specified conditions of stream flow
and temperature.  Thus the model turns out to be totally
deterministic,  and  the variability of conditions  is handled  in
this analysis by assuming  extreme conditions usually associ-
ated with  substantial  declines in water quality. This is a
weakness in programming-type models,  and an alternative
mode of analysis which can handle some stochastic elements
(but with unfortunately its own set of  weaknesses) is dis-
cussed in  connection  with the Potomac case  in  the next
section.
  A linear programming  model  of  the general  type just
described  was constructed for the Delaware estuary.  In
addition to DO, it included other, nondegradable, types  of
material. Computation of the atl's is, as noted in the previous
chapter,  easier for these. Once done, the model provided an
extremely flexible tool for  the analysis of alternative policies.

Analysis of Objectives

A major part of the strategy of the Delaware study was to use
the model to  analyze  the  total and incremental  costs  of
achieving five  'objective sets', each representing a different
package  and  spatial  distribution  of water-quality  charac-
teristics,  with   the level of quality  increasing  from set 5
(representing 1964 water  quality) to set 1.  In some runs,
154
                     2-72

-------
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
          Economic Studies of Water-Quality Management

  overall costs were minimized by the programming model. In
  others, additional constraints were added to represent more
  usual  administrative approaches to the problem. The water-
  quality characteristics and associated levels and the areas to
  which they apply are shown for objective set 2 in Table 12.

  Table 12. Water-Quality Goals for Objective Set 2'
     WATER
     QUAL'TY  .   -

    FAHAMETERt
                                       I   i       *
                                III       n
   Du»iv«( oxv9"nt   55
                            5 5 1 4 0
                                  «0|50       5J)»5
                                    1           1
   00*1 -6/15
   ,nd 9/16 -12/31
   Chlondwf
              j *OQOU 4000| SOQOtl  5000"
                                                       5000"UoOOTT
   Tufb«J'lY (Tut     N L.*30
                                                       N 1_«30 N 1- N.L.
   pHTtlpHunitil    6.M.S
   pHtT 5/30 -9/15      7-85    | 6 5-8 5
                                                       63 15     7-a.S
   AIMin.iy tt    i 20 SO        20-50| 20-120
   H»rdnt«ff     , 95
                            »|TH>
   Tempwiturttt (°F)  Prncni lev* I
     x>l!|f      '0001       0001  0.005      OOOSjOOl
   Sv«Jnj|f       OS
' mg/1 unton SMC* futf   TtAtof Jnt

IMifOTXjm t$-d*Ymm

rang*  ^| Montftfy n*«n
                                                    ISummar

                                                    c in

                                                   HJL.
SOURCZ : Allen V. Knecse and Blaire T. Bower. Managing Water Quality: Economics
Techno tc^y. Institutions. Baltimore. Johns Hopkins Press. 1968.


                                                               155
                            2-73

-------
Economics and the Environment

The thirty  sections referred  to  in the table are shown o
Map 1. An effort was then made to measure benefits associated
with the improvement in water quality indicated  by the
successive objective sets. Before turning to the benefit estima-
tion, it  will be useful to describe the  objective sets  a bit
further.


Map. I. Map of the Delaware Estuary Showing Analysis Sections

  N                                  _\      ^TRENTON
                                             Miles
SOURCE: Federal Water Pollution Control Administration, Delaware Estuary
Comprehensive Study, 1966.

156
                        2-74

-------
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
   I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
         Economic Studies of Water-Quality Management

   Table 13 shows several water-quality parameters with the
   sedated levels for the five objective sets. The general nature
 "•f the objective sets is as follows:
 V' Obiective Set 1. This is the highest set. It makes provision
 for lar°e increases in water-contact recreation in the estuary.
 It also makes special provision for 6.6 p.p.m. levels of dissolved
 0>xygen to provide safe passage for anadromous fish during the
 spring and  fall migration periods. Thus this objective set
 should produce conditions in which water quality is basically
 no obstacle to the migration of shad and other anadromous
 (migratory) fishes.
   Objective Set 2. Under this set the area available for water-
 contact recreation is constricted somewhat. Some reduction in
 sport and commercial fishing would also  be expected because
 of the somewhat lower dissolved oxygen  objective. This set,
 like objective set 1, makes special provision for high dissolved
 oxygen during periods of anadromous fish passage.
   Objective Set 3. This set is similar to set 2. Although there is
 no specific  provision  for raising  dissolved oxygen during
 periods of anadromous fish migrations, there is compara-
 tively  little  difference  in  the  survival  probability under
 objective sets 2 and 3. Under the waste-loading conditions
 envisioned for objective set 3, the estimated survival 24 out of
 25 years would  be at least 80 percent - compared with 90 per-
 cent for set 2.
  Objective  Set 4. This provides  for a slight increase  over
 1964 levels in water-contact recreation and fishing in the lower
 sections  of  the portion of the estuary  studied. Generally,
 water quality is improved slightly over 1964 conditions and
 the probability of anaerobic conditions  occurring is greatly
 reduced.
  Objective Set 5. This would maintain 1964 conditions in the
estuary. It would provide for no more than a prevention of
further water-quality deterioration.
  The costs of achieving objective sets 1 through 4 by various
combinations  of waste discharge reduction at  particular
outfalls for the waste-load conditions expected to prevail in
                                                      157
                       2-75

-------
Table 14. Summary of Total Costs (millions,  1968 dollars) of Achieving Objective Sets 1-4 (costs include cost of
maintaining present (1964) conditions and reflect waste-load conditions projected for 1975-80)
Flow at Trenton = 3,000 cubic feet per second

Objective
set
1

2

3

4

Uniform treatment
Capital
costs
180

135

75

55


O&M
costs*
280
(190)
180
(12-0)
80
(5-5)
57
(5-0)

Total
CObtS
460*

315*

155*

130

Zoned treatment
Capital
costs
180

105

50

40

\
O&M
costs*
280
(190)
145
(100)
70
(4-5)
40
(2-5)

Total
costs
460'

250*

120*

80

Cost
Capital
costs
180

115

50

40


minimization
O&M
costs*
280
(190)
100
(70)
35
(?.-5)
25
(1-5)


Total
costs
460*

215*

85*

65


  • Operation and maintenance costs, discounted at 3 percent twenty-year timt horizon; figures in parentheses are equivalent annual operation
and maintenance costs in millions of dollars/year.    t High-rate secondary to tertiary (92-98 percent removal) for all waste sources for all prosranu.
Includes in-stream aeration cost of 520 million.    1 Includes $1-52 million for either sludge removal or aeration to meet goals in river
sections 4*3 and #4.
SOURCE: Allen V. Kneese and Blaire T. Bower,  Managing Water Quality. Economics, Technology. Institutions, Baltimore, Johns Hopkins
Press. 1968.
     Table 15. Costs and Benefits of Water-Quality Improvement in the Delaware Estuarv Area* (million dollars)













Objective
set
I

2

3

4

Estimated
total
cost
460

215-315

85-155

65-130

Estimated
recreation
benefits
160-350

140-320

130-310

120-280
Estimated incremental
cost

minimum*

245

130

20

maximum*

145

160

25

Estimated incremental
benefits

minimum*

20

10

(0

maximum'

30

10

30












      • All costs and benefits are present values calculated with 3 percent discount rate and twenty-year time horizon.
      t Difference between adjacent minima.    J Difference between adjacent maxima.
    SOUUCE: Allen V. Kneese and Blaire T. Bower. Managing Wa,tr Quoltiy: Economic,, Technology. Invitation.,, iwifmoro. Johns llorthn Pres*. |»*».
                                                     2-76

-------
   I
   I
   I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
Economics and the Environment

produce the specified quality levels at about half the
cost of the uniform treatment method. Especially at the hn>t-,e,
quality level, the cost saving is of a highly significant rragrv'
tude. The present  value of the cost stream saved is mV-
order of 3150.000,000. The result occurs because, as we sa\T>"
Chapter 5, the incentive effect of the charge is to concentrate
discharge reduction where costs are lowest.

Table 16. Cost of Treatment under Alternative Programs
objective
(p.p.m.)
2
Program
LC
1-6
7-0
UT SECh
(million dollars per vear)
5-0
20-0
2-4
120
ZECh
2-4
8-6
  The least-cost system is capable of reducing costs somewhat
further  than either the  uniform or the zoned charge since it
programs  waste discharges  at  each point specifically in
relation to the cost of improving quality in the critical reach,
but this comes at the cost of detailed information on treatment
costs at each point and  a distribution of costs such that some
waste dischargers experience heavy costs and others virtually
none. The least-cost system is closely approached by ZECh
at the higher quality level. In effect, this zone charge procedure
'credits' waste  dischargers at locations remote from the
critical  point with degradation of their  wastes in the  inter-
vening  reach of a stream befote they arrive at  the critical
reach. This is a necessary condition for full efficiency when
effluent charges are used to  achieve a standard at a critical
reach in  a stream. The  reason that the ZECh does not
achieve quite the same  efficiency as the least-cost  program is
that the 'credit' is not specific to the individual waste discharger
but is awarded in blocks - three in this case.
  Another way of putting this  is that  equalizing marginal
164
                     2-77

-------
             Economic Studies of Water-Quality Management

  \     .^te-water-reduction cost at all outfalls is strictly speaking a
  I    n-"-essary condition for cost minimization only when a homo-
      '      'lump' of assimilative capacity is being allocated - or
          formally, when all the coefficients in the transfer matrix
                ng to a binding constraint are identical. When they
      #6 not, thorough-going cost minimization requires that prices
      be 'tailored' for each outfall. This explains why the solution
      j,3seci on a single charge only approaches but does not reach
      t[,ie programmed cost minimization  solution. How closely it
      will approach is an empirical question relating to  the magni-
      tude of the fli/s.
       Having the tool of transfer coefficients in hand we can now
      treat this matter more rigorously than was done in Chapter 5.
      Assume two industrial dischargers  with the following  cost
      functions for reducing waste discharge:

      (1)                     
-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
Economics and the Environment

If we include the  constraint R9 — 06i*i + ae2x2, we have
3 equations and 3 unknowns (xlt x2, and /).
Solving for A, we get:
(7)
and
(8)
Note that:


or

A = — -£

ae2 dx2.

1 dci 1 dc2
061 
-------
        Economic Studies of Water-Quality Management

 plus cost of treatment - is about  the  same as the cost of
 treatment only under the uniform treatment program. About
 half of this outlay does not represent an actual resources cost
 but rather a rental-type payment for the use of assimilative
 capacity.
  It should be noted that an important efficiency advantage of
 the effluent charges programs as contrasted with the least-cost
 program is their relatively smaller demand for information and
 analytical refinement. A study of the type already performed
 for the Delaware  estuary could serve as the basis for an
 effluent charge scheme. An order-of-magnitude estimate of the
 required charge reveals itself. Actually,  since the costs do not
 take account of the possibility of process change in industry,
 which is  often cheaper than 'end of pipe' treatment, the ten
 cents per pound of BOD charge was probably too high and
 could be  adjusted downward at a later point (one would need
 to take inflation into account). Also, the charge provides  a
 continuing incentive for the discharger to reduce his waste
 load by placing him under the persistent pressure of monetary
 penalties. He is induced to develop new technology and as  it
 develops  to implement it. As new technology develops, the
 effluent charge could be gradually  reduced while the stream
 standard is maintained,  or the standard could be allowed to
 rise if this is deemed desirable. The process of induced tech-
 nological change has particularly striking results in this field
 since  the waste assimilative  services of watercourses have
 heretofore been completely unpriced.
  The  direct  control  measures implicit  in  the  least-cost
 program, on the other hand (as well as the effluent standard
 of the uniform  treatment program), provide only  a more
 limited incentive to improved  technology.  Moreover,  the
 minimum cost  program would requiie not only  detailed
information on current cost levels at each individual outfall,
 but also information on changes in cost with changing tech-
nology, in  regard  to   industrial  processes,  product mix,
treatment cost, etc., and would be extremely inequitable in its
cost distribution.

                                                     167
                            2-80

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
Economics and the Environment

  The Delaware estuary survey was  a pioneering study of
water-quality management and is of continuing importance
Some of the tools it developed are in use by the Delaware
River Basin Commission, and it is still frequently referred to
in discussions of policy in  the United States - a point I win
develop a little later in the chapter. It was the first study to
embody  at  least  a rudimentary  ecological model  into an
economic optimization  framework,  and it  provided  an
illuminating  analysis  of  several  policy  options including
effluent charges.
  The study did  have some major  deficiencies,  however.
Among them are  that only a very limited range of tech-
nological alternatives for managing  water quality was exam-
ined and that the stochastic aspects  of water quality were
not analyzed. These matters were considered, however, in the
Potomac study to  which I turn next. Before  doing so how-
ever, I must introduce one additional piece of methodologi-
cal equipment - stochastic  or probabilistic   generators of
hydrological records.

Stochastic Hydrology

As everyone knows, the flow of rivers (one of the major
determinants of their capacity to assimilate waste materials) is
not constant with time. It varies  seasonally in  somewhat
regular patterns but with a large random component. Tradi-
tionally,  in designing flow regulating structures (reservoirs)
an empirical device called a 'mass curve' is used to determine
the yield that  can  be sustained  from the reservoir during
drought periods. Underlying this technique is the assumption
that future flows (measured on a daily or monthly basis) will
be an exact replication of flows observed historically (usually
there  are thirty years  or so of good records in the more
advanced countries).
  An alternative, that is more defensible on statistical grounds,
is to assume that  the  historical record is  a sample  from a
much larger population and that what will remain invariant in
168
                  2-81

-------
            Economic Studies of Water-Quality Management

     .   future are only certain of the moments (mean, standard
    deviation, skewness)  of the distribution of observed flows.
    Based on the latter assumption, stochastic hydrology genera-
    tors have been devised which can simulate long hydrologic
    sequences incorporating extreme values and patterns of events
\   not in the historic record while maintaining selected moments
    of the frequency  distribution of  that  record.  There  are
    difficult problems associated with such generators, but many
    of them have been overcome. The problems  involve such
    things as serial correlation in the record of flows and main-
    taining cross  and  serial  correlations  for  separate gauging
    stations in the same system. I will not  attempt to treat these
    since my intent is just to acquaint the reader with the general
    recursive relationships used.
      In these 'Markovian'  models the  basic recursive relation
    used can be represented by the following equation8:
    In this model, *(+l, the flow in the (/ + l)st interval, is a
    linear function of xt, the flow in the ith interval; of a stan-
    dardized random deviate /(+1;  and of the population  para-
    meters p (the population mean), a (the population standard
    deviation), ft (the regression coefficient of flows in the (i + l)st
    interval on values in the j'th interval), and P (the correlation
    coefficient  between flows in successive  time periods). The
    standardized random deviate ti+i has  zero mean and unit
    variance.
     It can be shown that if the distribution of flows is normal
    and the regression functions of xt on *,_i is linear and homo-
    scedastic (of constant variance), the conditional expectation
    of x,, given xt-i, is given by
   and the expected variance of xit given xt-i, is
                   Var(jf, 1 .x.-O = a2(l - p2).

     Thus, we can see in the recursive equation that the first two
                                                        169
                           2-82

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
I
        Economic Studies of Water-Quality Management

   In 1963, the U.S. Army Corps of Engineers submitted the
 Potomac River Basin Report. This report was the first one in
 which  a fedeial water resource agency submitted a 'compre-
 hensive'  plan in  which water-quality management was the
 major  consideration. The plan  took  a  quality  objective
 stated in physical  terms (parts per million of dissolved oxygen)
 as given, and recommended a program of waste treatment and
 low-flow regulation to meet this objective in the future. While
 it was  a  pioneering effort, the benefit evaluation techinique,
 based on the 'alternative cost procedure', was grossly deficient,
 and the  range of alternatives considered for water-quality
 improvement was still very narrow, even though wider than
 that included in the Delaware study. Basically, the Corps of
 Engineers  limited its  planning  to consideration  of those
 quality improvement facilities which could clearly be imple-
 mented through  existing governmental  institutions.  As we
 shall see, this restricted the range of choice greatly and led to
 the recommendation of a set of facilities which was far from
 the least costly which could have been devised to achieve the
 stated water-quality objective.
  A later Resources for the Future study,10 which forms the
 basis foi  my  further discussion, used the Corps of Engineers
 data plus  considerable  additional information  to define
 further the range of alternatives for water-quality management
 in the Potomac estuary in the neighborhood  of Washington,
 D.C., the locus of most of the water-quality problems.

 The Basin and Its  Problems

The watershed of the Potomac, an area of about 14,000 square
miles,  lies  in portions of four  states and  the  District  of
Columbia. About  three quarters of the population in the basin
is found in the Washington  metropolitan area. This area,
which extends beyond the District of Columbia into Maryland
and Virginia, already has a  population  of nearly 3 million
persons and is one of the most rapidly growing metropolitan
areas in the nation. The Washington area lies near the head of
                                                     171
                         2-83

-------
Economics and the Environment

terms on the right-hand side are the expected value of ,YUI>
given Xi  has occurred (February's flow, January  having
occurred),  and the last term is the random component con-
sisting of a randomly selected normal, deviate which, when
multiplied  by the expected variance of x\ + \, given xt, brings
the result back into the proper dimension comparable with the
first two terms of the right side. It can also be shown that to
treat non-normal distributions it  is sufficient to  alter  the
distribution of the random additive component and thus
maintain higher moments of observed data.9
  It is readily seen that a recursive model of this type could be
used to generate indefinitely long sequences of hydrological
record to be used as  inputs to a simulation model. As long a
generated sequence of flows as is wished (say, several thousand
years) can  then  be used in  analyzing the probabilistic per-
formance of a reservoir, or other water quantity and quality
management system elements. Stochastic hydrology is used in
connection with the Potomac case study to which I now turn.

The Potomac Study

A 1961  amendment to the Federal Water Pollution  Control
Act of 1948, which, with minor exceptions, was the first step
by the United States Federal Government into what had been
an exclusive area of state sovereignty, is the starting point for
discussion of the Potomac case. The feature of the 1961 Act
which is most relevant to present purposes is that it provided
for the inclusion of subsidized storage in federal multi-
purpose reservoirs to augment low flows for the  purpose of
improving water quality. This opened the door to the possi-
bility of  including  in  federally  subsidized water-quality
improvement  programs technological  options  other than
treatment.  Naturally this  possibility drew  the attention  of
federal agencies engaged in the planning and construction of
public works related to water resources. In the eastern United
States the U.S. Army Corps of Engineers is the lead agency
in this respect.

170
                      2-84

-------
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
I
Economics and the Environment

the Potomac estuary which  is heavily  used for recreation
Water supply for the area is taken from the Potomac n\er
above the estuary. The estuary periodically experiences a !ow
level of dissolved oxygen - a condition which could get much
worse as waste loads from the metropolitan area and upstream
sources mount. The Corps of Engineers as part of its plannin°
effort projected water demands and waste loads to the year
2010. One of the central objectives of the plan was to control
the effects of waste loads expected to prevail then. Among the
planning assumptions was that the maximum feasible control
of waste loads would result from conventional  secondary
sewage treatment (about 90 percent BOD removal).
  The plan made public in 1963 recommended the construc-
tion by the  year 2010 of sixteen  major reservoirs in the
Potomac  basin and  more  than 400 headwater  structures
(see Map  2). These  were meant to  meet  projected  water
supply,  water-quality, and flood control objectives. Of the
sixteen major reservoirs, ten were planned to meet projected
upstream  objectives  for the low-flow regulation  for  water
supply and quality control. At  the same time, this group of
reservoirs would provide a higher sustained flow at Washing-
ton sufficient to meet the projected municipal water diversions
there. The remaining group of six reservoirs (providing 60 per-
cent of the proposed  yield - 2340 c.f.s. (cubic feet per second)
out of 3931 c.f.s.) was  designed to augment flows into the
estuary  sufficiently to maintain  4 p.p.m. of dissolved oxygen
(twenty-four-hour monthly mean for the minimum month).
The projected storage was based on counteracting residual
2010 waste loads and an assumed replication of the historical
record of flows  into the estuary (i.e., the mass curve approach
was used to determine requited storage  to sustain flows cal-
culated to be needed to offset residual waste loads to the extent
of maintaining 4 p.p.m. DO). From a statistical point of view,
the  mass curve approach has great deficiencies which were
discussed  in  connection with our earlier consideration of
stochastic hydrology. I will return to this point a little later.
  A benefit-cost analysis was presented which indicated  that
172
               2-85

-------
        Economic Studies of Water-Quality Management

 ,i,e benefits from flow regulation would outweigh its costs.
 out  this analysis did not do what benefit-cost analysis  is
 •ntended to accomplish - assist in deciding whether a pro-
 *,{ap 2. Major Reservoirs in Recommended Plan for Potomac
 Basin
SOURCE: PRB Report, Vol. I, p. 30, reproduced in Robert K. Davis, The Range of
Choice in Water Management (Baltimore, Johns Hopkjos Press, 1968).
posed investment is socially worthwhile. The preset physical
quality objective of 4 p.p.m. of DO was taken as given in the
planning. It was assumed that treatment of the sewage from
the Washington  metropolitan area  could not succeed in
removing more than  90 percent  of the waste load. This  is
insufficient   to  meet  the  objective.  The  only alternative

                                                      173
                                2-86

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
I
Economics and the Environment

seriously investigated was low-flow regulation to improve the
waste  assimilative capacity of  the  estuary. Benefits  from
low-flow regulation were taken  to be the cost of a single-
purpose reservoir designed to meet low-flow requirements at
each point of  projected need without  regard  to  the  com-
plementary effects of  meeting upstream  needs.  Moreover
costs of the alternative reservoiis were calculated at a higher
rate of interest - presumably because it was assumed they
would  be implemented by state  or local governments which
have to pay higher rates  of interest than the federal agencies
use in  their own calculations.
  This string of planning assumptions was bound to produce
positive net  benefits for flow regulation. But this result was
obtained without even addressing the real question - whether
the 4  p.p.m. objective was justified  by the willingness of
beneficiaries to  pay at least as much as it costs to maintain it.
Clearly, the  benefit-cost analysis as it was  performed is not
helpful in deciding whether the plan is justified.
  Furthermore, for various reasons having to do with limita-
tions on  the authority  of water resources agencies and their
perception of problems and appropriate solutions, the  plan-
ners made no concerted or systematic effort to search for and
evaluate alternative ways (in addition to flow regulation) of
achieving the specified  water-quality objective. The measures
recommended for quality control were limited to basic con-
ventional  treatment and low-flow augmentation - measures
which could clearly be  implemented by the federal and local
government agencies which  are the traditional purveyors of
water services in the United States. To  have implemented a
program embodying the less conventional measures which the
later Resources  for the Future study demonstrated would have
entered into  a cost-minimizing solution  and  would  have
required institutional change. The possibility of such change
was not  contemplated in the planning process.  Failure to
consider  institutional reform as  a possible objective of the
planning process is a failing frequently  encountered around
the world and I shall have more to say about it subsequently.
174
                 2-87

-------
             Economic Studies of Water-Quality Management

      Searching for Additional Alternatives

      The follow-up Resources for the Future study showed that if
      the plan had included certain collective measures - which no
      existing agency had a clear authority or incentive to finance,
      construct, and operate - it would have entered into a least-cost
      svstem for meeting the oxygen objective. Had  such a system
      served as  the alternative  for benefit analysis, net benefits for
      flow regulation, at least for the larger-scale reservoir systems,
      would have been grossly negative. But, in general, the alter-
      native cost-benefit estimation procedures are  inappropriate
      in cases like this.
        In going through the later analysis, the Corps assumption
      that wastes in  the  Washington metropolitan  area  would
      receive 90 percent treatment was (somewhat arbitrarily) used
      as a baseline. The costs of other alternatives were then weighed
      off against the incremental cost of flow regulation for counter-
 ,     acting the residual oxygen deficit.
 !       Costs were obtained for different levels of low-flow regula-
 ;     tion by scaling down by various amounts the Corps's proposed
      low-flow regulation system. The scaled-down systems were
 ;     roughly optimized by using a computer simulation program
 i     which permitted the  historical trace of hydrology  to be
      regulated  by the various  systems.
        The line between simulation models and the optimizing type
      of programming  models, such as that used in the Delaware
      study, is often not very clean cut. In genera], however, simula-
|     tions are used to play out the implications of certain assump-
,'     tions, (reservoir sizes, operating rules, etc.) either solely in
|     terms of the behavior of the natural system upon which they
I     have an impact or on certain  economic variables - such as
|     costs. Normally they do not contain an explicit optimizing
t     procedure but simply enumerate a large number of alterna-
f     live results. This is a problem because the number of possible
      alternative results can easily become unmanageably large.
      This was  not so in the case of the Potomac study, however,
      because the range of variables was carefully limited and only
                                                           175
                                 2-1

-------
I
I
I
I
I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
  I
  I
   I
   I
   I
   I
Economics and the Environment

large increments were permitted. The advantage of
tion is that  it can more easily  handle non-linearities  a-M
probabilistic aspects of problems  than can mathematical pr'
gramming.
  In  the first  set  of Resources for the  Future analyses
historical hydrology was used to maintain close comparability
with the Corps results. In computing costs for the successively
smaller reservoir systems, account was taken of the difference
in flood damage reduction and recreation services realized bv
any scaled-down system in comparison to  the full proposed
Corps of Engineers system.
  Costs of several alternative ways of equivalently offsetting
the waste load were also developed. These included processes
for further treatment  of the waste load (microstraining, step
aeration, chemical polymers, powdered carbon, and granular
carbon); costs for effluent distribution via pipeline along the
estuary to make better use of its natural assimilative capacity;
and re-oxygenation of the estuary which, like low-flow regula-
tion, improves assimilative capacity.
  Computer simulation of the effects of these processes in view
of variations of river flow (using the historical hydrologic trace)
into the estuary show that they need to be operated on the
average only three and a half months per year in order to meet
the DO objective. Because the alternative systems are high in
operating cost  and low in capital cost relative to  low-flow
regulation, they can be comparatively efficient if operated only
as needed  but  would not be  competitive if operated  con-
tinuously, thereby overshooting quality goals most of the time.
Accordingly, they could only enter efficiently into the quality
management system if institutional means existed for care-
fully  articulated  design and operation in  conjunction  with
other elements of the system.
  Establishing combinations which would meet the standard
required that if one process was  reduced another had to be
equivalently  increased. It  was  possible to use computer
simulation to exhaust  all possible combinations of the feasible
and sufficient processes given the relatively large increments
176
                       2-89

-------
         Economic Studies of Water-Quality Management

      d for them. The computer program gave a complete
      and cost ranking of all systems - some 300 in all.
   A sampling of alternative feasible and sufficient systems is
 shown in Table 17.
 " This analysis shows that many combinations of processes
 could achieve  the objective at less cost  than the proposed


 Table 17- System Costs by General Class of Process Combinations.
 Three and a Half Months' Operation (present worth, fifty-year
 period, 4 percent discount in S million)

    Alternative systems
    1.  Reoxygenation                                20
    2. Chemical polymers and reoxygenation            22
    3. Step aeration and reoxygenation                  25
    4. Microstrainers and reoxygenation                28
    5. Diversion and  reoxygenation                    33
    6. Diversion, waste treatment and reoxygenauon      45
    7. Low-flow augmentation and reoxygenation        60
    8. Low-flow augmentation, reoxygenation and
      waste treatment                                60
    9. Low-flow regulation                           140

 SOURCE : Adapted from various tables in Robert K. Davis, The Range of Choice in
 Water Management. Baltimore, Johns Hopkins Press, 1963.
system based upon conventional treatment and flow regula-
tion. It is notable that all of them except the flow regulation
alternative would require the construction and closely articu-
lated operation of facilities which have not traditionally been
in the purview of either  the  federal or local government
(particularly reoxygenation and regional effluent distribution
works). Another salient point is that while low-flow regulation
is vastly more costly than reoxygenation or some of the other
alternatives, from the point of view of the people in the basin
it costs much less, because of subsidies. Low-flow regulation
for water-quality improvement is a fully  nonreimbursable
purpose of federal water development in the United States,

                                                      177
                            2-90

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
        Economic Studies of Water-Quality Management

   d to check that the yield of the proposed reservoirs system
   u]d be sufficient to meet the objective. As has already been
  Orcd. this analysis makes the statistically untenable assump-
  'on that future stream flow will be a replication of the past.
   To  help illuminate the  probability aspect  of the water-
 auaiity standards conventionally used in planning, a stochastic
 hvdrology was generated for long periods of time and applied
 to the reservoir simulation program.
   Table 18 presents some figures for the  different probabi-
 lities of violating  2 and 4 p.p.m. DO levels when different


 Table 18. Percentage of Time Monthly Mean DO is less than
 2 p.p.m. for Five-hundred-Year Trials at Different DO Target
 and System Capacities
Storage DO target
capacity p.p.m.
82,000 acre-ft
140,000
600,000
770,000
970,000
2
2
4
4
4
Percentage of
time < 2 p.p.m.
0-25
0-03
0-35
0-22
0
Percentage of
time < target
0-25
0-03
3-30
1-03
0-33
SOURCE : Robert K. Davis, The Range of Choice in Water Management. Baltimore.
Johns Hopkins Press, 1968.
systems of reservoirs are operated to achieve DO targets. In
this presentation it is assumed that low-flow regulation is the
only means used to counteract the residual deficit after about
90 percent treatment.  This is done to spell out clearly the
implication for reservoir storage, even though in an optimized
or least-cost system the incremental costs of achieving lower
probabilities of violation would be less. It is interesting to note
two main points emerging from this analysis.
  (1) Reducing  the probability of violating  the 4 p.p.m.
objective from  3-3 percent  to 0-33  percent  costs about
370,000 acre-feet in storage and around 50 million in dollars.

                                                       179
                           2-91

-------
Economics and the Environment

while no subsidy at all is available for measures like reo
genation and waste diversion. Thus, the fact that federal w •-"
development policy is such that certain measures for develop
ment confer large subsidies on a region while otheis do not J*
also contribute to choices among  alternatives  which a-
distorted from a broader economic point of view.
  Both of these factors were undoubtedly implicit considera-
tions in the plan recommended by the Corps. It is thus possible
to examine  the existing institutional and policy restraints bv
means of economic systems analysis which is not limited bv
these restraints, and thus provide information on trie desira-
bility of institutional change. Such examination of institutional   j
constraints clearly should be part of the planning process. In   '<
the case of the Potomac it appears that much could be gained   i
by  institutional arrangements permitting the  design  and   ;
operation of quality management systems embodying a wide
range of alternatives.                                       !

Stochastic Aspects

So  far, in my discussion of cases, I dealt with deterministic    i
models. These, quite imperfectly, recognize the variability of    1
river flow by specifying some level below which flow is unlikely    j
to drop. The Delaware estuary study took this approach and
so did  the Corps study of the Potomac, as well as  much of the    !
Resources for  the Future follow-on  study. But  the availa-    '
bility of the Potomac reservoir simulation model made it    j
possible to study some aspects of the probability question in a
more explicit  way. It is  one of the major disadvantages of   ;
optimization models such as that used on the Delaware estuary
(which as already mentioned otherwise have great advantages)   ;
that it is very difficult to  incorporate stochastic aspects into
them.
  The  Corps of Engineers based its design on the specification
that DO concentrations in the estuary would  not fall below
4 p.p.m. based on the twenty-four-hour monthly mean for the
minimum month. A standard kind of mass curve analysis was
178                                                        ]
                      2-92

-------