QUESTIONS AND ANSWERS f^. T ..-_ .1.._ - RETURNABLE BEVERAGE CONTAINERS FOR BEER AND SOFT DRINKS July 1975 1. What are returnable beverage containers? Returnable beverage containers are containers that are accepted for return after use. Usually a cash deposit is paid when the beverage is purchased and refunded when the container is returned. The purpose of the deposit is to provide an incentive for the return of the container either for refilling or for recycling of the container materials. 2. What are the environmental and resource conservation benefits of returnable beverage containers? The return of beverage containers reduces the generation of beverage container waste and litter. Reuse and recycling of containers reduces air and water pollution resulting from the production of containers, and conserves energy and materials. 3. What is mandatory beverage container deposit legislation? Mandatory deposit legislation is a law or ordinance which requires a deposit on all beverage containers sold in a particular jurisdiction, 4. Is there mandatory deposit legislation in existence today? Three States have enacted mandatory deposit or returnable container laws for beer and carbonated soft drinks: Oregon, Vermont and South Dakota. In Oregon, a refund value of 2 cents is carried by all "certified" containers, which can be reused by more than one manufacturer. All other containers carry a refund value of 5 cents. Metal containers with detachable tab tops are banned. ------- In Vermont, all beer and soft drink containers carry a refund value of at least 5 cents. The manufacturer or distributor is also required to pay the retailer a fee of 20 percent of the deposit (1 cent per 5 cent-deposit container) to cover the costs of handling the returned containers. In January 1977 nonrefillable bottles will be banned in Vermont, as will metal containers with detachable tops and non-biodegradable container carriers. South Dakota has passed a law which requires that every beverage container sold in that State, subsequent to July 1, 1976 shall be either a reuseable container or a container which is biodegradable. Several communities including Bowie, Maryland; Loudoun County, Virginia and Ann Arbor, Michigan have passed similar laws which have not been implemented due to legal challenges. 5. Does mandatory deposit legislation eliminate the use of the metal can as a beverage container? Mandatory deposit legislation does not prohibit the use of metal cans. However, in Oregon, after passage of the law, the use of refillable bottles increased and the use of cans decreased. For soft drinks, refillable bottles increased from 53 percent of the market prior to the law to 88 percent of the market in the year following the law.1 Soft drink cans decreased from 40 percent of the market to 12 percent.2 Refill able beer bottles increased from 31 percent of the market before the law to 96 percent after- wards. Beer cans declined from 40 percent to 3.5 percent. The use of nonrefillable glass bottles was practically eliminated for both beer and soft drinks. In Vermont comprehensive data on pre-law and post-law container useage is not available. However, as of April 1975, cans and nonrefillable bottles were still being sold for both beer and soft drinks, but a trend towards more wjdescale use of refillable bottles for soft drinks has been reported.5 Nationwide in 1972 approximately 39 percent of all soft drinks were packaged in refill able bottles, 27 percent in nonrefill able bottles and 34 percent in cans.6 For beer the figures are approximately 18 percent for refillable bottles, 24 percent for nonrefill able bottles and 58 percent for cans.7 The market mix of containers varies significantly for different geographic regions. ------- Mandatory deposit legislation would probably result in a shift towards the increased use of refill able bottles. Nonrefiliable glass bottles may well disappear from the market (however for larger sizes nonrefillable bottles may remain). Cans would probably decline in market share but would remain in some quantities, especially in areas where they are currently predominant. 6. How much solid waste can be prevented by such laws? On a national basis, beer and soft drink containers accounted for 8 million tons of solid waste in 1973.° This represented 6 percent of total municipal (household and commercial) waste. Beverage containers are a rapidly growing segment of municipal waste, with an estimated growth rate of 10 percent per year from 1962 to 1972.9 x If 90 percent of the containers bearing a deposit were returned ^> for refilling or recycling, there would be a reduction in beverage container waste of 70 to 75 percent, or 5 to 6 million tons on a national basis. ~%j 7. What about littered beverage containers? ^ Most studies show that beer and soft drink containers comprise t/-> between 20 to 30 percent of roadside litter by item count.10'']»12 ^; However many other littered items are smaller and less visable r^ than beverage containers and degrade more rapidly in the natural ^ environment. On a volume basis, which is a better measure of litter visibility, beverage containers have been found to represent 62 percent of highway litter.'' For the year following enactment of deposit legislation, beverage container litter decreased by 66 percent in Oregon and by 67 percent in Vermont.13'5 8. How much energy could be saved by use of returnable containers? Beverage containers that are refilled or recycled save energy and materials. A glass beverage container used 10 times consumes less than one-third of the energy of nonreuseable containers used to deliver the equivalent quantity of beverage.14 Aluminum and all- steel cans that are recycled save 78 and 39 percent, respectively, of the energy required to manufacture a can from virgin raw materials.1^ The energy that would be saved through mandatory legislation depends upon the resulting container mix and the return and recycling rates for the containers. For example, if national mandatory deposit legislation had been in effect in 1973, and if the bottle and can container mix had not changed, and if 90 percent of all bottles had been returned and refilled and 80 percent of all cans had been ------- recycled, approximately 151 trillion British Thermal Units (BTU) of energy would have been saved. If on the other hand in 1973 refillable bottles had represented 80 percent of the market share (and bottle and cans had been returned and recycled at the above rates) approximately 209 trillion BTU's of energy would have been saved.16 9. How significant are these energy savings? A saving of 209 trillion BTU's is equivalent to the energy content of 39 million barrels of oil. It is also equal to about one-half of the energy used in producing the current mix of beverage containers, While this amounts to a saving of just 0.3 percent of total national energy use, it is important to note that it is of similar magnitude to the saving achievable through other energy conservation measures currently being considered. For example, it is equivalent to one- half of the energy saving that can be achieved from strict enforcement of a 55 mile per hour speed limit nationwide.!7 10. How much materials could be saved through the use of returnable containers? If in 1973 90 percent of all bottles had been refilled, and 80 percent of all cans had been recycled, between 5 and 6 million tons of raw materials would have been saved that year. This would represent a savings of 3.8 to 4.6 million tons of glass, 1.1 to 1.3 million tons of steel and 300,000 to 350,000 tons of aluminum.16 11. How would a returnable system affect beer and soft drink prices? Beer and soft drinks sold in refillable containers are generally cheaper to the consumer than beverages in one-way bottles and cans. Savings in the range of $.03 to $,05 per 12 ounce container have been frequently observed.1**' '» However, it has been argued that the costs of handling and transporting returned containers are not fully reflected in retail prices. These costs have been estimated to range from less than $.01 to $.02 per container.22,23 Therefore, even if these costs are assumed not to have been reflected and are added, beverages in refillable containers cost less to the consumer. To the extent that mandatory deposit legislation induces a shift to refillable bottles, average prices for beer and soft drinks should decline. However, it should be pointed out that a rapid widescale shift to an all refillable bottle system would require considerable equipment changeover in the brewing and soft drink industries and would result in additional costs that could be passed on to the consumer. If the transition to refillables takes place gradually over a period of years, the costs of rapid changeover would be avoided. ------- 12. How many times do containers have to be returned before energy and cost savings are achieved?' For an energy saving to be achieved from use of a refillable bottle, it must make at least four trips or have a return rate of 75 percent.24 Refillable bottles generally become cheaper than one-way containers at return rates of 80 percent (5 trips), although this varies from bottler to bottler.25 In Oregon one year after passage of the deposit law, refillable soft drink containers were returned at a 96 percent rate,2^ and refillable beer containers at an 80 to 95 percent rate.2''2** Approximately 65 to 70 percent of all cans were being returned and this rate was increasing.26,28 Detailed data are not available from Vermont, although several bottlers have indicated return rates of 90 to 95 percent.5 The subject of average national return rates for refillable bottles is a matter of considerable debate. An estimate calculated by dividing container fillings by container purchases results in an average return rate during the period 1963 to 1972 of 94 percent for soft drinks and 96 percent for beer.29 These figures may not represent actual return rates since bottle inventories may have been changing. Furthermore, these figures include both "on-premise" beverage consumption (in taverns and restaurants) where return rates would be expected to be higher than for "off-premise" consumption (e.g. beverages purchased from supermarkets or retail stores). Another estimate indicates soft drink container trippage of 10 to 1530 (return rate of 90 to 94 percent) and a beer container trippage of 183' (return rate of 95 percent). In any case, for a mandatory deposit system it appears reasonable to expect a return rate for beer and soft drink containers that would be much greater than that necessary for energy and cost savings. 13. How would a mandatory deposit law impact on the beverage production, container manufacturing and distribution industries? The impacts of mandatory deposit legislation upon industry would depend upon the extent of the change in the market mix of containers and the time period over which this change takes place. Most estimates of economic impact have been based upon the extreme assumption of a complete and sudden switch to refill able bottles. Under these circumstances, facilities for the production, storage and distribution of one-way containers, not convertible to returnable systems, would become obsolete and would have to be replaced. Glass and metal container production would decline. Bottlers and brewers would initially have to invest in additional bottle washing equipment and refillable container lines. Additional transportation costs would ------- be incurred for the distribution of beverages and the return of containers. Some retailers would need additional storage space and would have to add employees to handle returned containers. Based on 1969 data in an industry-sponsored study of the impacts of a ban on nonrefillables, tax writeoffs would amount to $1.3 billion, and total new investments $1.2 billion. More recently the brewing industry has claimed total "conversion costs" of $5 billion for a sudden switch to refillables and a ban on one-way containers.33 The 1969 study indicated that cost increases in the brewing and soft drink bottling industries would be more than offset by container cost savings.3^ Some of these sayings could also be passed on to beverage distributors and retailers to offset increased costs in these sectors. The study found that the aggregate cost to all sectors of the industry (beverage producers through retailers, inclusive) would be $250 million in the first year of a ban, but would actually become a $40 million gain in subsequent years due to container savings. Tax losses and new investment requirements would be lower for a mandatory deposit system in which nonrefillable containers were not completely eliminated. Capital losses would be reduced if time were allowed for normal amortization of current investments over a period of years. A 1975 study for the State of New York, assuming a 3 year phase-in to a market mix of 80 to 90 percent refillables, concluded that new investment requirements in that period would be $53 million per year, compared to a normal investment requirement of $30 million per year with no legislation.35 It should also be noted that normal industry competition resulting in changes in relative container prices or introduction of new container types (such as the plastic bottle) could have similar impacts on the container industries. 14. What would be the effect of National mandatory deposit legislation on employment? The impact of mandatory deposit legislation upon employment would also depend on the rate of change of container useage. A rapid shift toward the use of refillable bottles would eliminate some jobs, primarily skilled positions in the container manufacturing industries. It has been estimated that a complete ban of nonrefillable containers in 1969 would have resulted in the loss of 60,000 jobs that year. However it was also estimated that the establishment of a returnable system would also create a roughly equal number of new jobs, primarily jobs of lower skill classification and pay, in the retail and distribution sectors of the economy. It is important to note that the employees displaced would not be directly transferable to ------- these new jobs. Employment dislocations would be reduced if nonrefiliable bottles and metal cans continued to be sold or if the change in container useage took place over a period of time. A transition period would allow natural attrition in employment to absorb some of the job losses. Also it would provide time for employment to shift to other plants or industries manufacturing other containers or similar products. For example, it has been estimated that a gradual transition over a 5 year period to a 90 percent reduction in nonrefillable containers would result in the loss of 39,000 positions.37 A 10 year transition to a similar market would result in the loss of about 17,000 positions.37 Studies conducted for the States of Maryland, Minnesota, New York, Connecticut, Illinois, Michigan and Maine all found that the job gains in the retail and distribution sectors would be greater than the losses in container manufacturing.38'44 in New York, for example, a job gain of 5,200 and a loss of 1,200 jobs was predicted, with a net annual payroll increase of $35 million.45 In Oregon, where a deposit law is in effect, one study estimated an addition, of 175 to 200 new jobs and a loss of 340 to 427 existing jobs but did not estimate job increases in retail stores.4^ Another study estimated a net job gain of 365 jobs (including retail).47 15. Is mandatory deposit legislation at cross-purposes with plants built for the recovery of energy and materials from waste? A resource recovery plant processes mixed municipal waste in order to extract materials and other products which can be sold. Changing the composition of municipal waste through mandatory deposit legislation would not significantly affect the economics of most resource recovery plants. Approximately 80 percent of the municipal waste stream is organic materials—paper, plastics, etc. This fraction should be the primary concern of a resource recovery facility, as it represents the bulk of the waste, and provides the bulk of revenue ($10 to $15 per ton of waste processed) needed to make resource recovery economically feasible.48 As a maximum result of mandatory deposit legislation, glass in the waste stream could be reduced by about 35 to 45 percent, ferrous metal wastes could be reduced by 15 percent, and, where use of aluminum cans is substantial, aluminum wastes could decline by 30 to 45 percent. Under favorable market conditions, gross revenues from the beverage container fraction of the waste stream amount to about $1 to $2 per ton of waste processed. When the costs of recovering and transporting these fractions are considered, the net revenue contribution is considerably less. Removal of the ------- 8 beverage container fraction through a mandatory deposit system would probably not cause a net revenue reduction in excess of $1 per ton of waste processed.49 It should be emphasized that recovery technologies for glass and aluminum are for the most part not yet fully demonstrated and markets for recovered glass and metal resources have just begun to be developed. In light of the uncertainties of separating and marketing aluminum and glass from solid waste, beverage container legislation does not entail undue risk for the installation of resource recovery facilities. Resource recovery system feasibility should not be decided solely on the basis of glass, aluminum and steel recovery economics. Other more important factors are the general uncertainty regarding future markets (especially for the organic fraction) and the insti- tutional obstacles to organizing and implementing a venture of this sort. A significant number of future recovery investment decisions should not be adversely impacted by mandatory deposit legislation. 16. Are there other mechanisms, such as the litter tax enacted by the State of Washington, that will achieve benefits similar to a mandatory deposit law? Litter taxes are generally very small taxes (a fraction of a cent per product) imposed at the time of sale of products likely to be littered. Such taxes could provide additional revenues to collect litter along streets, highways, and recreational areas. The major shortcoming of a litter tax is that it does not create a disincentive for littering (the tax is paid regardless of whether the individual purchasing the product litters the item or not). Furthermore, such a mechanism would not reduce the generation of solid waste, nor would it result in savings of energy or materials. Thus while a litter tax is not incompatible with mandatory deposit legislation, it is not a substitute for such legislation. 17. Is there a sanitation problem in storing used containers? While there is a possibility of insect problems associated with the storage of bottles and cans containing beverage residues, it should be noted that returnable containers have been used for many years without significant adverse public health impacts. If public health laws and sanitation codes are strictly enforced, and containers are picked up on a frequent and timely basis, such problems should be minimized. ------- 18. Isn't there a loss of convenience to the consumer? A deposit law does not require return of the container, but does make the consumer who discards the container pay the amount of the deposit. A study for the State of Oregon found that 87 percent of those surveyed found no inconvenience with returnables.^O Furthermore this survey found that 91 percent of the respondents approved.of the legislation and only 5 percent voiced any disapproval at all.51 19. What is the position of the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency on mandatory deposit legislation at the Federal, State and local levels? The U.S. Environmental Protection Agency has testified in favor of the adoption on a nationwide scale of a mandatory deposit system for beer and soft drink containers.^ Based upon several years of analysis and observations in the States which have enacted mandatory deposit laws, it is concluded that a mandatory deposit program would result in significant conservation of energy and materials, and a reduction in solid waste and litter caused by beverage containers. A sudden shift to a returnable system, however, would likely result in excessive economic disruption and unemployment. To minimize the adverse economic repercussions, it is recommended that a nationwide system be phased in over an extended period of time. While ideally such legislation should be national, State-level legislation, based upon the experience in Oregon and Vermont, also appears to be effective in achieving the benefits. Below the State-level, ordinances requiring mandatory container deposits would probably be effective in large regions, counties or metropolitan areas. Not enough experience has been acquired to indicate whether local ordinances for smaller communities would be effective. EPA neither supports nor opposes State or local deposit legislation. EPA favors national legislation in this area and has decided not to promote the adoption of State or local laws, which may be super- seded by a national law at a later time. Furthermore the Agency does not have the resources to analyze the economic impacts of different State laws. However EPA does not oppose State or local deposit legislation that is designed to reduce negative employment and economic impacts and contains provisions anticipating possible national laws. ------- References 1. Applied Decision Systems, Inc. Study of the effectiveness and impact of the Oregon minimum deposit law. Legislative Fiscal Office, Salem, Oregon, 1974. p. II-3. 2. Applied Decision Systems. Study of the Oregon deposit law. p. II-4. 3. Applied Decision Systems. Study of the Oregon deposit law. p. 11-67. 4. Applied Decision Systems. Study of the Oregon deposit law. p. 11-68. 5. Loube, M. Beverage containers, the Vermont experience. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Washington, D.C., 1975. Draft. 6. Franklin, W. E., and D. Hahlen, W. R. Park and J. M. Urie. Baseline forecasts of resource recovery, 1972 to 1990. Midwest Research Institute, Kansas City, Missouri, 1975. p. 241. 7. Franklin, W. E., Baseline forcasts. p. 255. 8. Smith, F. A. Technical possibilities for solid waste reduction and resource recovery: prospects to 1985. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Washington, D.C., 1975. (In press.) p.5. 9. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency calculations from Franklin, W.E. Baseline forescasts. p. 79, 98. 10. Applied Decision Systems. Study of the Oregon deposit law. p. 1-31. 11. Bingham, T. H., and P. F. Mulligan. The beverage container problem. Washington, U.S. Government Printing Office, 1972. p. 30. 12. Scheinman, T. Mandatory deposit legislation for beer and soft drink containers in Maryland, an economic analysis. State of Maryland Council of Economic Advisors, 1974. p. 3. 13. Applied Decision Systems. Study of the Oregon deposit law. p. 1-26. 14. Hunt, R. G., and W. E. Franklin. Resource and environmental profile analysis of nine beverage container alternatives. Environmental Protection Publication SW-91c. Washington, U.S. Government Printing Office, 1974. p. 21. 15 Hunt. R. G., and W. E. Franklin. Resource and environmental profile analysis, p. 40. 16. U.S, Environmental Protection Agency calculations from data presented in References 6 and 14. ------- 17. Personal communication. National Science Foundation to H. Samtur, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, April, 1975. 18. Dildlne, R. and R. Rainy. Impacts of beverage container regulations in Minnesota. Minnesota State Planning Agency, St. Paul, Minnesota, 1974. p. 14. 19. Environmental Action, Inc. Washington, D.C. Press Release. October 17, 1974. 20. Stern, C., E. Verdieck, S. Smith, and T. Hedrick. Impacts of beverage container legislation on Connecticut and a review of the experience in Oregon, Vermont and Washington State. Report to the Connecticut State Legislature, 1975. Final Draft, p. 28. 21. Smith, J. L. President, Coca-Cola, Inc. Hearings before the Subcommittee of the Judiciary, United States Senate on S.3133, August 8, 1972. Washington, U.S. Government Printing Office, 1973. p. 164. 22. Alpha Beta Acme Markets, Inc. Bottle survey 1971: a California supermarket report on the cost of handling returnable soft drink bottles. La Habra, California, 1971. 23. SCS Engineers. Solid Waste Management in retail food stores. Long Beach, California, 1973. p. 111. 24. Hunt, R. G. Resource and environmental profile analysis, p. 38. 25. Stern, C. Impacts of container legislation on Connecticut, p. 5. 26. Applied Decision Systems. Study of the Oregon deposit law. p. II-4. 27. Applied Decision Systems. Study of the Oregon deposit law. p. 11-68. 28. Gudger, C. and J. Bailes. The economic impact of Oregon's bottle bill. Oregon State University Press, Corvallis, Oregon, 1974. p. 24, 26. 29. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency calculations from data presented in Reference 6. 30. Franklin, W. E. Baseline forecasts, p. 247. 31. Franklin, W. E. Baseline forecasts, p. 256. 32. Mai Hie, J. The National economic impact of a ban on nonrefillable beverage containers. Midwest Research Institute, Kansas City, Missouri, 1971. p. 2. ------- 33. United States Brewers Association, Inc. Resource/energy recovery and recycling vs. source reduction: A simple economic analysis of two basic resource conservation strategies. Prepared by R. S. Weinberg & Associates, St. Louis, Missouri, 1975. 34. Mallie, J. National impact of a ban on nonrefillable containers. p. 35. 35. Quinn, R. R., and S. F. Sloan. No deposit no return... A report on beverage containers. New York State Senate Task Force on Critical Problems, Albany, New York, 1975. p. 7. 36. Bingham, T. H., The beverage container problem, p. 59. 37. Average of estimates presented in: Employment dislocations data. Research Triangle Institute memo to the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, April 10, 1974. 38. Scheinman, T. Mandatory deposit legislation in Maryland, p. 10-16. 39. Impact of beverage container regulations in Minnesota, p. 76-83. 40. Stern, C. Impacts of container legislation on Connecticut, p. 3. 41. Quinn, R. R. No deposit no return, p. 68. 42. Folk, H, Employment effects of the mandatory deposit regulation. Illinois Institute for Environmental quality, 43. Ross, M. Employment effects of a ban on nonreturnable beverage containers in Michigan. Kalamazoo Nature Center for Environmental Education, Kalamazoo, Michigan, 1974, p. 1-15. 44. O'Brien, M. Returnable containers for Maine: an environmental and economic assessment. Maine Citizens for Returnable Containers. Portland, Maine. 1975. 45. Quinn, R. R. No deposit no return, p. 5. 46. Applied Decision Systems. Study of the Oregon deposit law. p. iii. 47. Gudger, C. Economic impact of Oregon's bottle bill. p. 69. 48. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. Third report to Congress; resource recovery and waste reduction. (Draft) p. 130. 49. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency calculations based upon estimate of solid waste stream composition, material recovery processing costs and revenues. 50. Applied Decision Systems. Study of the Oregon deposit law. p. Ill - 38. ------- 51. Applied Decision Systems. Study of the Oregon deposit law. p. III-6. 52. Quarles, J. R. Statement of the Deputy Administrator, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency before the Subcommittee on the Environment, Committee on Commerce, U.S. Senate. Washington, D.C., May 7, 1974. ------- ------- |