PNNL-
              Second Generation Model 2004: An Overview
                                      By

                                 Jae Edmonds1
                                 Hugh Pitcher
                                  Ron Sands
                                   October
                                     2004
Prepared for the United States Environmental Protection Agency under
Contracts AGRDW89939464-01 and AGRDW89939645-01
Joint Global Change Research Institute, College Park, MD
Pacific Northwest National Laboratory
Operated by Battelle for the US Department of Energy

-------
Acknowledgements:  The initial conceptual work for the Second Generation Model began in
1990, with implementation starting in 1991. Since then many sponsors and staff have contributed
to the model development. Prominent among the sponsors have been the US EPA, presently
through the Economic Analysis Branch of the Climate Change Division, Office of Atmospheric
Programs, the Integrated Assessment Program widiin the Office of Science, US Department of
Energy, and the Electric Power Research Institute, Climate Change Program.

1 The authors are researchers at the Pacific Northwest National Laboratory, Joint Global Change Research
Institute at the University of Maryland, College Park campus. The authors are indebted to many others for
help and support in the development of this report, including: Antoinette Brenkert, Charlette Geffen,
Sonny Kim, Ray Kopp, Dina Kruger, Michael Leifman, Richard Richels, Michael Shelby, Steven J. Smith,
Gerry Stokes, John Weyant, and Marshall Wise. The authors have also benefited from a long list of
collaborators and colleagues from around the world, whom we will not attempt to enumerate here, but all of
whose contributions are appreciated.
LEGAL NOTICE

This report was prepared by Battelle Memorial Institute (Battelle) as an account of sponsored
research activities. Neither Client nor Battelle nor any person acting on behalf of either:

MAKES ANY WARRANTY OR REPRESENTATION, EXPRESS OR IMPLIED, with respect to
the accuracy, completeness, or usefulness of the information contained in this report, or that the
use of any information, apparatus, product, or composition disclosed in this report may not
infringe privately owned rights; or

Assumes any liabilities with respect to the use of, or for damages resulting from the use of, any
information, apparatus, process, or composition disclosed in this report.

Reference herein to any  specific commercial product, process, or service by trade name,
trademark, manufacturer, or otherwise, does not necessarily constitute or imply its endorsement,
recommendation, or favoring by Battelle. The views and opinions of authors expressed herein do
not necessarily state or reflect those of Battelle.

-------
                      Second Generation Model 2004: An Overview
                                     I. Introduction

The Second Generation Model (SGM) is a computable general equilibrium model designed
specifically to analyze issues related to energy, economy, and greenhouse gas emissions. It has
fourteen global regions, multiple greenhouse gas emissions, vintaged capital stocks, explicit
connections between technology and the economy, explicit treatment of energy and land stocks
and is disaggregated to reflect the relative importance of sectors in determining greenhouse gas
emissions.  Model development began in 1991.  The first model design paper was published in
1993 (Edmonds, et al., 1993). The SGM was developed to complement the '"first generation
model," referred to as the MiniCAM. The MiniCAM was also explicitly designed to address
long-term, strategic issues related to energy, economy, and greenhouse gas emissions (Edmonds
and Reilly, 1983)2 and continues to be used for that purpose. In contrast the SGM was designed
to address transitional energy-economy-technology-greenhousc-gas-emissions issues.

This paper documents  the present version of the SGM: SGM 2004. The SGM 2004 consists of a
theoretical structure, computational implementation, and statistical expression.  This paper
documents the theoretical structure and some  of the most important data shaping model behavior.
It does not attempt to document the software employed to solve the statistical expression of the
theoretical relationships nor does it provide a  complete documentation of all of the data employed
in SGM 2004. The SGM was developed at the Pacific Northwest National Laboratory (PNNL)
and is maintained by the PNNL  Joint Global Change Research Institute (JGCRI)3.

The SGM theoretical structure reflects the specific issue the model is designed to address.  Thus
SGM emphasizes both economic principles, which lead to the selection of a neoclassical
computable general equilibrium (CGE) framework, and specific economic sectors, especially the
energy sector. Both play important roles in shaping the SGM structure.

SGM 2004 is a direct descendent of the model described in Edmonds et al. 1993.  Needless to
say, SGM 2004 has evolved substantially over the last decade. The SGM was designed from the
start to address the climate problem with particular focus on greenhouse gas emissions and their
relationship to the economy. To understand the structure of the SGM and why particular aspects
of economic activity were chosen and others given lesser emphasis, one needs to understand the
relationship between emissions of greenhouse related gases and climate change.  Physical science
relationships play a major role in shaping which aspects of the economy are emphasized and
which are deemphasized in the SGM.

In Section II we discuss the relationship between climate change and the design of the SGM. The
SGM has been designed with capabilities that may not yet be implemented. That is, it is designed
to be capable of being extended without any substantial change to model structure.'' Section II
2 The MiniCAM evolved to include agriculture, land-use, terrestrial and ocean carbon cycle, radiative
forcing, sea level rise, and climate change. See Appendix D for a brief comparison of the MiniCAM and
the SGM.
3 The JGCRI is a collaboration between the PNNL and the University of Maryland at College Park. The
JGCRI is located on the campus of the University of Maryland in College Park, MD.
4 From the start SGM design has sought to create a flexible modeling structure with capabilities that may
only be implemented in later expressions of the model. The transformation of the SGM from a Fortran-
based code to a C++ based code takes this approach a  major step further by creating a completely data-

-------
therefore focuses on structure and capability.  Section III focuses on the mathematical
formulation of the model. Section IV addresses the data that populate SGM 2004, and Section V
discusses the model as it is currently implemented.


                         II. The Climate Problem and SGM Design


The overriding design philosophy of die SGM is build the model to address a specific problem.
The climate issue has a variety of important characteristics that make it different from traditional
pollution problems. The following characteristics are critical:

    •  Climate change is global. Unlike local and regional environmental issues, radiative
       forcing is driven by the concentration of greenhouse gases in the atmosphere, which in
       turn is determined by the present and prior emissions of all sources everywhere in the
       world. This is particularly true for the atmospherically well-mixed gases such as carbon
       dioxide (COi), nitrous oxide (N2O), methane (CH4), chlorofluorocarbons (CFCs),
       hydrofluorocarbons (HFCs), perfluorocarbons (PFCs)  and sulphur hexafluoride (SFe).  It
       is also true for extremely short-lived gases such as sulfur aerosols and black carbon.
       While these gases do not mix completely, they are emitted in sufficient quantity to affect
       the energy balance of the planet.  Beyond radiatively active gases, other gases such as
       carbon monoxide (CO)  and volatile organic compounds (VOCs) affect the energy
       balance of the planet indirectly by affecting the concentration of other greenhouse gases
       such as CH4 and ozone  (Oa).  The SGM was designed  to produce estimates of global
       emissions of all anthropogenic  greenhouse related gases.

    •  Emissions occur across heterogeneous global regions.  Greenhouse gases are emitted
       under a wide range of local circumstances.  Two of the world's largest emitters of COi
       are the Untied  States and China5. These two regions have dramatically  different
       economies. Emissions of greenhouse gases are distributed unevenly around the world.
       Ten nations and the European Union account for more that 75 percent of global emissions
       of fossil fuel CO2. The SGM was disaggregated by region to enable it to explicitly
       consider major greenhouse gas emitting regions6.

       SGM model development was pursued using regional  research partners. Major SGM
       regions were developed through an explicit collaboration with a partner institution
driven model.  Thus, the addition of sectors or inputs or markets to the model within the original modeling
framework becomes merely a matter of data inputs and entails no additional code. This is analogous to a
building with rooms that have not yet been occupied.
3 The United States for example, is modeled as a market economy. Cliina on the other hand has a
substantial history of investments that occurred under a period of cenlral planning. The vintage structure of
the SGM helps address this difference. India, another major fossil fuel carbon emitter, is a mixed economy
requiring special treatment of investment decisions.
6 The SGM regions are: United States, Western Europe, China, Former Soviet Union, Japan, India,
Canada, Korea, Mexico, Australia & New Zealand. Brazil, Eastern Europe, Mideast and Rest of the World.
These regions correspond to the major fossil fuel carbon emitters.  In 1999 fossil fuel carbon emissions
were as follows: United Slates (25%), European Union (14%), China (13%), Russian Federation (6%),
Japan (5%), India (5%), Canada (2%), Korea (2%), Mexico (2%), Ukraine (2%), and  Australia (2%). The
inclusion of the Eastern Europe region enables the SGM to match the structure of major international
agreements such as the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change UNFCCC (United
Nations, 1992) and the Kyoto Protocol (United Nations, 1997).

-------
       resident in the region7.  This ensured that regional elements in the SGM explicitly
       considered important regional characteristics, and insured an enhanced understanding of
       regional data. Because data availability is heterogeneous the SGM was designed so that
       each region could be disaggregated to different levels of sectoral detail. While a set of
       commodity aggregates that trade internationally were fixed, those aggregates could
       reflect differing degrees of underlying sectoral disaggregation in each region. Investment
       behavior was also allowed to differ from region to region. Investment behavior in India
       was not assumed to be the same as in the United Slates.

       Climate change is a long-term issue that must be addressed at multiple time scales.
       Radiative forcing is determined by the concentrations of greenhouse gases in the
       atmosphere, not emissions rates. The importance of this distinction varies from
       atmospheric constituent to atmospheric constituent. For black carbon, the distinction is
       unimportant.  For short-lived gases there is a relationship between steady-state emissions
       rates and steady-state atmospheric concentrations. For the long-lived gases and CO2 the
       distinction is critical. The concentration of CO2 is determined by cumulative emissions,
       at least on time scales of 1000 years or less.1* The SGM was thus designed to go fifty
       years or more into the future.

       Technology development and deployment occurs on decadal  scales.  It can take fifty
       years for a technology to increase its market share from one percent to 50 percent
       (Hafele, 1981; DeCanio and Lailner, 1997). The SGM was designed to encompass the
       time scale of technology transitions.

       But policy occurs on a much shorter time scale.  The Kyoto Protocol (United Nations
        1997)5  proposes limitations that would enter into effect over the period 2008 to 2012, a
       five-year time frame, but a decade after its negotiation.  The McCain-Lieberman Bill
       (S139,  2003) focused on the period 2010 to 2016. The SGM was designed to assess
       policy proposals that are framed on time scales that are ten to fifteen years into the future.

       Policy intervention proposals can also take many forms ranging from fiscal instruments
       to cap-and-tradc to regulatory regimes to combinations of regimes.  See for example
       SI 39 (2003). The SGM model structure was designed to be capable of examining the
7 Model development partnerships were as follows: Canada, University of Victoria; Western Europe
Centre International de Recherche sur rEnvironmnent et Ic Developpement; Japan, National Institute for
Environmental Studies; Australia and New Zealand, the Australian Bureau of Agricultural and Resource
Economics; Korea, Korean Energy Economics Institute; Former Soviet Union, Center for Energy
Efficiency; China, China Energy Research Institute; India, The Indian Institute for Management; Mexico,
Universidad Nacional Autonoma de Mexico, Colegio de Postgraduados and Mexicano Instituto del
Petroleo.
8 This is the consequence of the fact that fossil fuel carbon was removed from the atmosphere millions of
years before the present and stored in geologic formations. Reintroducing carbon from the geologic
reservoir into the fast cycling ocean-atmosphere-terrestrial system adds to the stock cycling in those three
pools. While it can take 1000 years or more for these three reservoirs to reestablish equilibrium, some of
the carbon is expected to remain in the atmosphere pool effectively permanently. On average
approximately 20 percent of carbon released into the atmosphere would be expected to remain more than
1000 years (Kheshgi, Smith and Edmonds, 2004).
9 The Kyoto Protocol remains a proposal as of this writing (August 2004) and has not entered into force.
The United States is not a party to the Protocol and has announced an independent approach to emissions
mitigation (Bush, 2002).

-------
        implications of explicit policy intervention ranging from fiscal policies to regulatory
        intervention.

        Long time scales cany other implications for model design as well. For example,
        analysis of CO: concentration stabilization scenarios reveals that for concentrations
        ranging from 350 ppm to 750 ppm10 that annual global emissions must peak and decline
        during the 21s1 century (Wigley et al., 1996. IPCC, 2001). This requires substantial
        departures from present technology deployment, potentially very substantial policy
        intervention, and dramatically different relative price regimes. Thus, the behavior of the
        economic system at points substantially removed from present and historical equilibria is
        an important SGM model design consideration.

        The SGM tracks historical capital stock by vintage.  The decision to produce from
        existing capital stocks differs from the decision to acquire and operate new investments.
        Ex post options are inherently  more limited than ex ante decisions.  Once in place, the
        ability of a sector to substitute between inputs is fundamentally more limited than before
        the choice  of a specific technology and capital investment. But, once in place, existing
        plant and equipment need only cover operating costs to continue to operate. Sunk costs
        are ignored.  Policies that lead to premature retirement of capital stock are reflected
        literally in the SGM.  That is, productive capacity in the form of existing plant and
        equipment is removed from the model. The SGM was designed to clear investment
        markets, track capital stocks, and insure consistency across the economy within a CGE
        framework.

        Greenhouse Emitting Human Activities Are Pervasive. Unlike simpler environmental
        problems, emissions of greenhouse related gases are associated with human activities
        across the entire economy. Energy alone is associated with virtually every aspect of
        human society  and an understanding of fossil fuel CO2 emissions requires an
        understanding of the global energy system from production to transformation to transport
        to end use. Land-use change is the next largest source of net COj emissions to the
        atmosphere after fossil fuel use.  Other greenhouse gases are associated with a variety of
        human actives, e.g. methane is emitted by ruminant livestock, wetland rice cultivation,
        landfills, coal mining, deforestation, and natural gas transmission and distribution. These
        human activities are interconnected.  For example, one response to emissions mitigation
        could be to expand production of commercial biomass energy11. An increase in the
        production of commercial biomass requires land.  Expanding land-use in turn can lead to
        expansion of land use into presently urunanagcd ecosystems. This in turn can lead to
        carbon fluxes from soils and existing carbon stocks. Such interactions can be significant.
        Similarly, under some policy regimes, reductions in carbon emissions can also reduce
        aerosol emissions leading to near-term warming. The SGM was therefore designed as a
        CGE model to  enable system interactions to be addressed explicitly and completely and
        to be consistent with economic principles.
10 Preindustrial (1750) concentrations were approximately 280 ppm.  If emissions ceased instantaneously,
the atmospheric concentrations would relax to approximately 300 ppm over the course of the next 1000
years, but would not return to preindustrial concentrations without a substantial program to remove CO2
from the atmosphere.
11 Commercial biomass energy is attractive because it is produced and consumed in the short carbon cycle.
That is, the carbon released in its oxidation was removed from the  atmosphere during the growth of the
plant. Growing and consuming commercial biomass fuels produces no direct net carbon release to the
atmosphere over the growth-consumption period. Of course, there can be indirect net carbon emissions.

-------
        Technology is a central feature shaping anthropogenic greenhouse emissions.  Given that
        technology is ''the broad set of processes covering know-how, experience and equipment,
        used by humans to produce services and transform resources" (Edmonds and Moreira,
        2004), technology is a central issue in understanding climate change.  Technology unifies
        the elements of the system.  Technology shapes many elements of SGM design.

        Model formulations—First, the SGM is a neoclassical CGE model and therefore can use
        technology represented either as production functions (the primal relationship between
        inputs and outputs) or as a dual cost or profit function (the dual relationship between
        prices of inputs and outputs).

        Emissions coefficients—Emissions can be associated with either inputs or outputs.
        Emissions are usefully  reported in physical units. The SGM was designed to track
        emissions at their point of release. For some greenhouse related gases, e.g. COzU
        emissions are associated directly with fuel use.  Thus, in the SGM CO; emissions are
        directly related to the fuel input13.  In other instances emissions are closely related to the
        output, e.g. CO; from cement manufacture.  For other emissions, e.g. NOX and fine
        particulates emissions are non-stoichiometric14.  The SGM was designed to address the
        breadth of emissions associated with different technologies and different greenhouse
        related gases.

        Hierarchical structure—Data are always the limiting constraint for modelers.  There are
        virtually no limits to the detail that modelers want. Yet data in the real world are limited.
        Furthermore, data that are available in one place may not be available in another. To
        address this reality the  SGM defined a data driven structure including markets, sectors,
        subsectors and technologies. Trade occurs in markets. Markets clear supplies and
        demands for a specific  product. The SGM  is designed to clear a user-defined number of
        markets.  The number of markets in SGM 2004 was chosen to best address questions of
        greenhouse related emissions and mitigation15.  Products are frequently associated with
        the aggregate output of a sector16.  The selection of sectors in turn is determined by
12 The traditional treatment of CO2 emissions is to measure the emission by its carbon weight. This is
unlike the traditional pollution measurement which would have counted the weight of the COj molecule
rather than the carbon atom only.  The reason Tor this convention is that regardless of the oxidation process,
all of the emission components are converted to CO} in a relatively short period of time. For example the
e-folding time for carbon monoxide removal from the atmosphere (transformation to CO2) is denominated
in months. Thus, the measurement of fossil fuel CO2 emissions depends only on the carbon-to-energy ratio
of the fuel and fuel use.
13 Average values of carbon emissions per unit of energy are: Natural gas, 13.7 TgC/BJ; Petroleum, 20.2
TgC/EJ; and Coal, 25.5 TgC/EJ. (TgC: teragrams of carbon = 1012 C, EJ: exajoules = 1018 Joules)
14 That is, emissions rates depend on the conditions under which the reaction takes place.
1  SGM markets are crude oil production, natural gas production, coal production, hydrogen production,
electricity production, oil refining, natural gas distribution, paper and pulp, chemicals, primary metals, food
processing, other industry and construction, the everything else (approximates services) sector, passenger
transport, freight transport, grains and oil crops, animal products, forestry, biomass production, other
agriculture plus a market for labor and loanable investment funds. In mitigation cases markets for
greenhouse gas emissions allowances can be formed.
16 A product can be supplied by more than one sector in the SGM. For example, the SGM 2004 has an
electricity market.  Electricity is the aggregate output of the electricity sector. However, it is also possible
for a manufacturing sector, such as petroleum refining,  to employ a technology that produces combined
heat and power, and excess power could show up as a supply of electricity from the petroleum refining
sector.

-------
                                 importance in addressing the climate problem17. In addition, the SGM defines subsectors
                                 and technologies as components whose output is aggregated to define sectoral
                                 production.  Production from technologies aggregate to total subsector production and
                                 subsector production aggregates to sectoral production. For example, the electricity
                                 generation sector as currently implemented has two sectors (base load and peak) and
                                 seven subsectors within base load labeled for the primary fuel input: oil, gas, coal,
                                 biomass, nuclear, hydro, and other renewables. The coal subsector can be disaggregated
                                 into electricity produced from various coal technologies such as for example, pulverized
                                 coal, integrated combined cycle coal gasification, and each of these can occur with or
                                 without a CC>2 scrubber. Since trade occurs at the level of markets, regions can have
                                 dramatically different degrees of technology detail at the subsector and technology levels,
                                 and still be compatible with the overall SGM system integration.

                                 Energy focus—Since CO2 is the most important greenhouse gas and energy the
                                 overwhelming determinant of anthropogenic C02 emissions, model design gives special
                                 prominence to treatment of the energy production, transformation and use.  CO2 as well
                                 as other greenhouse related emissions are directly associated with physical energy flows.
                                 Both energy stocks and flows are important  to the problem.  Stock concepts include
                                 resources and reserves, while flows include  production and consumption rates.
                                 Resources of energy include the total potentially available amounts that could be
                                 delivered from known and inferred sources using both presently available and potentially
                                 available technologies.  Once a resource is identified by place and  can be produced
                                 profitably with known technology it is defined as a reserve (a subset of the larger
                                 resource pool).  Production occurs out of reserves both in reality and in the SGMl 8.  The
                                 most important energy transformation is electric power generation. It is a major source
                                 of fossil fuel CO2 emissions and potentially one of the most important sectors in any
                                 emissions mitigation policy response. Technology substitution shapes this sector's
                                 response to any policy intervention. Electric power generation has a very wide array of
                                 technology options, motivating in part the hierarchical structure of the SGM. Similarly,
                                 transportation plays a special role  in greenhouse related emissions. The transportation
                                 sector is a major source of emissions, but unlike power generation  it is dominated by a
                                 single fuel, and is highly insensitive to a carbon value 19. Transportation emissions are
                                 largely determined by technology  availability.  Furthermore, substitution of energy for
                                 other inputs is limited in many processes. This in turn has influenced the choice of
                                 functional forms in the SGM.  SGM design emphasizes a detailed treatment of the energy
                                 sector.

                                 New investments, expectations and vintaged capital stocks—The SGM five-year time
                                 step and the importance of technology motivated an explicit treatment of capital.
                                 Whereas it is tempting to treat capital as a malleable factor input to all production
                         17 Sectors for SGM 2004 are described in the next section. They include: crude oil production, natural gas
                         production, coal production, hydrogen production, electricity production, oil refining, natural gas
                         distribution, paper and pulp, chemicals, primary metals, food processing, other industry and construction,
                         the service or everything else sector, passenger transport, freight transport, grains and oil crops, animal
                         products, forestry, biomass production, and other agriculture.
                           Obviously depletable resources (e.g. petroleum, natural gas, and coal) are treated differently from
                         renewable resources (e.g. wind and solar).  For the former the use of the resource is consumptive, while for
                         the latter it is not.
                         19 The provision of transportation services, e.g. passenger-miles, is dominated by non-fuel costs.  There are
                         few economically competitive options for fuel switching in the sector.
I

-------
        functions, the importance of technology in shaping energy transitions argues for a more
        sophisticated treatment. The SGM was designed to distinguish between existing capital
        and associated technologies and new investment options; it uses a vintaged approach to
        capital stocks.

        Production occurs out of existing capital stocks and technologies.  Technologies are
        described with a production function that prescribes the relationship between inputs to the
        production process and outputs. For existing vintages of the technology, capital is
        limited to the amount initially deployed. This also limits production from each existing
        vintage.  Existing vintages continue to be operated up to the point at which they can no
        longer cover their operating costs.  New plant and equipment is added to the economy
        each period. Technology options are described by ex ante production functions that
        describe the envelope of potential ex post production functions that can be deployed. The
        ex post production function differs  from the ex ante production function in that the
        substitution between inputs to the production process is more limited once a specific
        production function has been selected from within the ex ante envelope of possibilities.

        The selection of new investments depends  on expected profitability. Expected
        profitability in turn depends on both the suite of ex ante production relationships
        available and expectations about future input prices, output prices, fiscal measures and
        regulations.  The SGM is a recursive model and therefore expectations need not be
        realized.  Price expectations in the  SGM are variable, though the model defaults to
        myopic foresightZO.  Other options include expectations built upon past experiences and
        perfect foresight.  Combinations of the preceding are also possible.  For example it is
        possible to combine myopic foresight for prices with perfect foresight for other potential
        policy interventions21.  Assumptions about the formation of price expectations play an
        important role in the SGM.
                                HI. SGM Model Description

The previous section described the motivation for the SGM model structure.  In this section we
describe the model itself, beginning with an overview and concluding with a description of the
model's equation structure.

Overview of Model Structure

The SGM is a computable general equilibrium model that has been designed to address issues
associated with the emission of greenhouse gases to the atmosphere22. Figure 3.1 provides a
schematic of the key sectors of the economy that are interconnected in the SGM computable
genera] equilibrium framework.  On the left hand side of Figure 1 are two sectors that create final
*° Decision makers assume prices will remain iit then current levels indefinitely into the future.
*' The implications for ill formed expectations can also be explored. Decision makers can be given false
information, e.g. act as if there will never be a policy intervention, and model output and behavior can be
compared to the full-information alternative.  As yet the model has not been operated in full perfect-
foresight mode, though there is no reason this could not be done.
22 The SGM was designed to be a component of a larger integrated assessment of climate change modeling
system.  The role of the SGM was to provide a description of the human activities that generated
anthropogenic emissions and ultimately experienced the consequences of climate change. To date the
SGM has only been used to assess issues associated with the emission of greenhouse gases to the
atmosphere.

-------
demands for new net goods and services production in the economy, the household and
government sectors.  On the right hand side of Figure 3.1 are the sectors of the economy that
produce new final goods and services, the energy production and transformation, agricultural,
transportation, and industrial and services sectors2'. In addition to the production and
consumption of goods and services, Figure 3.1 indicates that the release of greenhouse related
emissions to the atmosphere are tracked by the point of release.  Gases include both CC>2 and non-
002 emissions.
                             Final Goods and Services
                                    Purchases of Rnal
                                    Goods and Services
                                           Greenhouse
                                             Related. :
                                            Emissions
                  Rnal Demand Sectors
                          Industrial Production &
                         Inter-Industry Transactions
            Greenhouse
              Related
             Emissions
                                       Payments to Primary
                                       Factors of Production.
      Primary Factors of Production

Figure 3.1: SGM 2004 Major Components.
The household sector makes decisions about four issues in the SGM: demographics, labor
supply, savings out of income, and the distribution of consumption among alternative goods and
services. The government sector consumes some final goods and services, and makes decisions
about policy including fiscal policies, subsidies, regulations, and income distribution.

There are 21 producing sectors in SGM 2004. For ease of discourse we have grouped these 21
producing sectors into four larger aggregates (energy production and transformation, industry,
transportation and agriculture), but as will become clearer as our discussion proceeds each of the
21 sectors is on a par with every other sector from the perspective of the model. The groupings,
23 Those who have either taught or taken Economics 101 will recognize Figure 3.1 as simply the classic
"circular flow" diagram used to describe an economy.
                                            10

-------
however, indicate relative emphasis within the SGM. Figure 3.2 gives an estimate of 2004 global
CO2 emissions and its distribution among sectors.
                 Agriculture-
                  Land-Use
                   1570.82
Building
  965
              Transportation
                  2,043
                   23%
           lectrlcity
            2,471
          Figure 3.2: Estimated 2004 Global Anthropogenic CO: Emissions by Sector

Figure 3.2 reveals that each of the SGM sectoral groups represents a significant fraction of
estimated global anthropogenic CO2 emissions. The bulk of emissions (82 percent) are associated
with fossil fuel use. The disaggregation of emissions by sector gives the largest single share to
power generation, followed by transportation and industry, with a smaller share associated with
buildings (the service and household sectors in the SGM). Since power generation is a derived
demand, the share associated with the buildings sector would be closer to those of industry and
transportation if electrical emissions were associated directly with the consuming sector.

About one fifth of anthropogenic CO2 emissions are associated with agriculture and land-use
change, principally deforestation and principally in the tropics. Emissions mitigation, however, is
not limited to reducing net deforestation and loss from soils. The sector can be a major source of
energy (growing commercial biomass as an energy feedstock) and has the potential to store
significant quantities of carbon in soils and above ground plantations.
                                            11

-------
       Figure 3.3: Anthropogenic and Natural Forcing of the Climate for the Year 2000,
       Relative to 1750
                      (Source:  IPCC, Third Assessment Report, 2000.)

What is not shown in Figure 3.1 is the relative importance of different greenhouse gases. As
discussed in Section II, the contribution of non-CO2 greenhouse gases can be significant. Figure
3.3 shows the estimated contribution of all atmospheric constituents that directly affect the
Earth's radiative energy balance.  (The contribution of gases such as CO, which affect the
radiative balance of the planet indirectly through atmospheric chemical reactivity, are not
estimated). What is clear from Figure 3.3 is that while CCb is the largest single contributor to
climate forcing in the industrial era, the non-CO2 greenhouse gases are associated with a large
contribution. Thus, the non-CO2 greenhouse gases cannot be ignored in  addressing climate
change.

If one considers only the gases of the United States emissions mitigation policy24 then the non-
CO2 greenhouse gases account for approximately 17 percent of United States emissions. Yet
their potential importance in addressing climate change is belied by that  aggregate statistic.
Emissions of the non-CO- greenhouse gases, and particularly methane, have declined at a more
rapid rate per unit of GDP than CO2 (EIA, 2000).  More importantly, the presence of each
molecule of a non-CO2 greenhouse gas in the atmosphere is generally associated  with a larger
change in radiative forcing than a molecule of CO2.  Mitigation of non-CO2 greenhouse gases can
therefore have a benefit in terms of climate change that is relatively large.  Furthermore,
mitigation of the emissions of short-lived gases, such as methane, can rapidly change the global
concentration of these gases and can therefore influence radiative forcing and global mean
surface temperature more rapidly than an equal change (in terms of tons  mitigated) in the
emissions of CO2.
24
  See http_;//www whitehpuse.goy/r
                                           12

-------
The SGM is a computable general equilibrium model. This modeling choice provides at least two
critically important advantages.  First, because a CGE model covers all economic activity, it is a
fully internally consistent representation of all economic activities. Given the breadth of
activities that are encompassed by the climate problem, it is a natural framework in which to
work.  Second, a CGE model applies economic principles to the climate problem.  Because
addressing the climate problem,  and particularly the emissions mitigation component, is a
problem of allocating scarce resources to competing ends, it is fundamentally an economics
problem.

In some ways a CGE model does the same things that any market oriented model does. It gathers
supplies and demands from all decision makers in the economy and adjusts prices until markets
clear.  What is different about a CGE model is that it adjusts all prices until all supplies and
demands in all markets are balanced simultaneously25. Effects in one part of the economy are
reflected throughout the rest of the economy in a way that is both internally consistent and
consistent with economic theory. Thus, quantities that are inputs to simpler, partial equilibrium
models, such as for example, Gross Domestic Product (GDP), are outputs of a CGE model.

The Production Function in the SGM

Production in  the SGM (the right side of Figure 1) is represented by a set of production functions.
Each of the production activities has a relationship between the set of inputs and its output26.
That is, we can describe an output, Y, as being produced by using any other produced output,
and/or any primary factor of production, capital, labor, land, or mineral resources, or

                                   Y = F(XUX2,   ,XN)

where  X; are the inputs from all 21 of the model's sectors of the economy (crude oil production,
natural gas production, coal production, hydrogen production, electricity production,  oil refining,
natural gas distribution, paper and pulp, chemicals, primary metals, food processing, other
industry and construction, the service sector, passenger transport, freight transport, grains and oil
crops,  animal products, forestry, biomass production, and other agriculture, plus the primary
factors of production, capital, labor, land, and mineral resources).  The relationship between
inputs  and  outputs is described by the function, F.

Of course,  F will be different for each sector. For some the relationship may be simple. For
example, in some instances it is a familiar mathematical form such as the Constant Elasticity of
Substitution (CES) production function27.  For others, it is a more sophisticated, hierarchical
25 In point of fact, if there arc N markets to clear, only N-l prices need be adjusted as one price must serve
as numeraire. This is known as Walras' Law.
26 In principle, the structure is sufficiently flexible that it can accommodate multiple outputs as well as
multiple inputs.
2' There are many production function relationships that are potentially available.  These range from the
CRS to the Translog (Christenson, Jorgenson, and Lau, 1971) to the Generalized Leontief (Diewert, 1971)
to the Generali/ed Cobb-Douglas, the Generalized CES (Edmonds and Reister, 1982) and there are many
more (Perroni and Rutherford, 1998).  Production functions have a variety of properties. An attractive
feature of production functions such as the Translog is that it is malleable.  That is it can match any
arbitrary neoclassical production functions to a second order at a point. This virtue is particularly valuable
in the analysis of historical patterns of behavior.  For models that are looking forward into the future,
regularity of behavior becomes increasingly important, particularly under circumstances where changes in
relative prices can be large. This is clearly the case for a model like the SGM which looks forward 50
                                             13

-------
relationship. Regardless, the principle is the same; at any point in time there is a well defined
relationship between inputs and outputs. In all instances F accounts for the existing deployment
of plant and equipment installed in prior time periods.

Given the relationship, F, and a set of assumptions about the nature of markets, for example, cost
minimization as the objective of producers, input and output markets are competitive,28 then the
demands for inputs can be derived. From the perspective of production then, this provides an
approach to derive both the demand by all sectors for all inputs in the production process, and the
supply of all goods to the market, for any set of prices at any point in time. Of course, the
demand for all produced goods plus the supply of primary factors of production from final
consumers and the government (the left hand side of Figure 3.1) are required to close the system.

Form of the Production Functions in the SGM

In a numerical model such as the SGM the production function takes on an explicit form.  The
SGM employs the Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) production function extensively.

The CES production function (Uzawa, 1962) can be written,
where gross output q is a function of inputs x and technical coefficients ag, 05, i=l,   , N. Nis the
number of inputs to production. Many subscripts have been suppressed for clarity; each sector,
subsector, and vintage combination has its own set of technical coefficients, p is a parameter that
controls the elasticity of substitution a according to

    tr=H(\-p)                                                                      (4)

One attractive feature of the CES is the fact that it can reflect a wide range of substitutability
between factors of production.  At one extreme the amount of each input required per unit of
output can be unchangeable.  This is sometime referred to as a Leontief production function. But,
it can also exhibit flexibility in substitution between inputs.  The degree of flexibility is
determined by the elasticity of substitution parameter, p.29
years into the future and which can contemplate relative prices that can vary an order or magnitude or more
from historical values.
28 That is, individual producers behave as if they can sell as much or as little as they want at the market
price, and can purchase as much or as little as they want of any input at the market price.  Existing capital is
the exception to that assumption. A production function using existing capital is limited to the amount of
capital that was installed at the time the production technology was brought on line.
29 This CES production function is written in a slightly different form from that in Edmonds et al. (1993).
This functional form makes it easier to describe technical change in the SGM, and more clearly shows the
relationship between CES production and fixed-coefficient (Leontief) production.  Edmonds and Reister
(1982) and Perroni and Rutherford (1995) have shown that nested versions of the CES production can
exhibit high degrees of flexibility while maintaining attractive global properties. The elasticity of
substitution in CES production functions has a practical lower bound of 0.05 in economic models such as
SGM. Elasticities less than 0.05 result in numeric overflows or underflows in double-precision Fortran.
Fixed-coefficient production functions in SGM have an elasticity of substitution of exactly zero.
Therefore, there is a range of substitution elasticities between zero and 0.05 that SGM cannot simulate.
                                             14

-------
As discussed earlier, if \ve add assumptions about the ability of agents to buy and sell as much as
they wish at market prices, plus the objective of minimizing the cost of production, then the
demand for each input to the production process can be derived as a function of its price and the
price of all other inputs.  This is expressed mathematically in equation (7), which describes the
demand for factors of production per unit output (input-output coefficients) as a function of
prices,
                     EL
                     Pi
                         \ r
                                                                         (7)
where a,y is the amount of input / required per unit of output/. Note that these CES input-output
coefficients always depend on prices.  Also note that the above equation uses subscripts for inputs
and outputs, except for the exponent r. This exponent actually does vary by producing sector, but
subscripts on r have been suppressed.30

                Table 3.1: jectors, Subscctors and Technologies in SGM 2004
Market:
Sector:
Subsector:




















ELECTRIC POWER
BASELOAD POWER
Gas
Natural Gas Combined Cycle
Natural Gas Combined Cycle
with Carbon Capture and Storage (CCS)
Coal
Coal Gasification Combined Cycle
Coal Gasification Combined Cycle with CCS
Pulverized Coal
Pulverized Coal with CCS
Nuclear
Light Water Nuclear Reactor
Hydro
Other Renewable
Geothermal
Solar (generic)
Wind (on-shore)
Wind (off-shore)
Municipal Solid Waste
Biomass
Biomass crop solids

PEAKING POWER
Oil
Gas



















JO-
  The corresponding CES cost function is

                          \ir


                II f
1
                    a.
where  r = p /(p — 1) and p, is an element of the price vector p.
                                                                         (5)
                                                                         (6)
                                            15

-------
Technologies are shown indented beneath each subsector.
As indicated above, the relationship between inputs and outputs can be relatively sophisticated.
Consider electric power generation in the SGM 2004 as shown in Table 3.1 above.
                             Electricity Generation
                           SGM-2004 nesting option
                                                               Wind-o«-a, oc.

                                                               Winder, shore
               Oil  Gas
               NGCC
                     NGCCccs    /     \      PCccs
                              Coal IGCC
Solids
(commercial blcmess)

Waste (municipal)
Hydro
Nuclear
                                        Coal IGCCccs
            Figure 3.4 SGM 2004 Nesting of Power Generation Technologies

For each of the technologies listed above, there is an individual production relationship between
inputs and the production of electricity.  The total production of electricity is the sum of
electricity production from all of the baseload technologies plus all of the peaking power
technologies31. Total demand for production from each of the other sectors, plus the demand for
labor and other primary factors of production is the sum of the demands from all of the baseload
power technologies plus all of the peaking power technologies.

Historical Capital and Vintaged Production

Technology is never static; it evolves with time. The history of technology development can be
seen in the distribution of previously deployed physical plant and equipment.  Some technologies
have been available for a century1 or more, e.g. electricity generation from coal. Other
technologies have become available only more recently, e.g. combined cycle natural gas turbines.
Other technologies remain to be deployed in commerce, e.g. coal gasification combined cycle
with carbon capture and  geologic storage. Yet even such long-lived technologies as electric
power from coal generation have changed and evolved. The pulverized coal plants installed in
the 1980s in the United States are fundamentally different from the plants deployed in the 1950s.

The SGM begins each period with a legacy of historical technologies and their associated plant
and equipment (which constrains total production from historical plant and equipment). The
SGM keeps track of capacity associated with each of the technologies.  For example, in the
electric power generation sector this includes tracking capacity for each of the technologies listed
31 It is worth noting that for electricity, physical production is additive. One base-load Watt-hour produced
using coal is perfectly substitutable with a base-load Watt-hour produced using natural gas. This may not
be true for other sectors, such as for example the Service sector.
                                            16

-------
in Table 3.1, in five-year intervals,  For many of these technologies in the base year,  1990, no
installed capacity exists.  For example, there is no coal gasification combined cycle with carbon
capture and geologic storage.  For other technologies, there is substantial capacity in every
vintage stretching back into history, e.g. pulverized coal.

The SGM has defined lifetimes for plant and equipment. Some old capacity is retired each
period32. The SGM solves every five years, and infers retirements over the entire five-year time
step since the previous solution year.  Prior to reaching retirement age, capacity is operated as
long as the owners can cover their operating costs. That is, once installed, returns to capital do
not affect the decision to operate. Owners of the plant and equipment may receive precisely the
returns they expected, or they may  earn much more, or they may receive less than expected when
the plant and equipment initially went into operation. Regardless, the plant and equipment is
operated as long as operating costs are covered33,34.

The Demand for New Plant and Equipment

In addition to existing capacity, the SGM also invests in new plant and equipment in each five-
year time step35.  This decision includes a consideration of all of the technology options
potentially available—their input requirements (including capital investment) and their
production, as well as expectations about the prices for inputs and outputs over the lifetime of the
plant and equipment36. Because there arc many potential options in which to invest, the SGM
n The lifetime of capital in SGM, while conceptually variable, is typically 20 years, or lour model time
steps. Existing vintages can be shut down before planned retirement if revenue is not sufficient to cover
variable costs.
33 This explains why for example existing nuclear power plants are some of the most profitable units in the
United States' electric utility system, while there has not been a new unit brought on line in decades.
34 At profit rates below a user specified value, the operating level of an existing capital stock will be scaled
back in order to maintain a continuous supply function, a necessary condition for the solution algorithm to
work.
35 Production of outputs and input requirements are denominated in terms of annual rates. As a
consequence, investments for years between any two five-year time steps are inferred by inrerpolation.
56 The technology or production function choice set before the fact can be quite large. Because any
potentially available technology can potentially utilized, the degree of substitutability between inputs to the
production process before a specific investment is made can be greater than after the fact. The relationship
between inputs and outputs potentially available before an investment is made is referred to as the ex ante
set of production possibilities, while the specific technology selected is said to contain the ex post set  of
production possibilities.
        The CES production function is employed to represent both the ex ante and ex post relationship
between inputs and outputs. An ex post production function is one that has been deployed in the economy.
Production in the SGM only occurs after a particular production function is chosen, that is an ex post
production function.
        New plant and equipment enter the economy at the time of investment. Investments are made
from the array of potentially available options.  For any technology the suite of all potentially available
technology options forms the ex ante production function. The ex ante production function is the envelope
of all potentially available ex post production functions. Needless to say the elasticity of substitution  of the
ex ante production function always exceeds that of the ex post production function.
        A wide range of price response is available by selecting various combinations of elasticities  for the
ex ante and ex post production functions. The four types of price response are putty-putty, putty-semiputty,
putty-clay, and clay-clay.
        At one extreme is the putty-putty relationship between the ex post and ex ante production
functions. A putty-putty technology uses the same elasticity of substitution for both new and old capital.
New capital  and old capital respond in the same way to changes in price. This can occur when there is only
one production function from which to choose.
                                               17

-------
assigns levels of investment based on expected profitability. That is, the demand for new capital
is determined by the expected contribution of that investment to the net worth of the sector37. The
expected profit rate is the discounted profit stream divided by the amount of capital invested.
Introducing a value for carbon increases the price paid for fossil fuels, which are inputs to
production. If other prices don't change, then the profit rate goes down for all production
processes that use fossil fuels. A carbon value, therefore, moves investment away from sectors or
subsectors that use fossil fuels as inputs.  Of course, the SGM only invests in sectors in which
expected profits are positive.

The default assumption for expectations is that current prices are anticipated to remain fixed, but
that future policy interventions are known with perfect foresight.  This  pair of assumptions is
arbitrary. There is no well defined method for determining price and policy expectations, though
there are competing representations.  In fact, there is no reason to presume that one  set of model
derived parameters can accurately predict expectations for future prices or policies.  The
prediction of price and policy expectation remains as much an art as a science. But, other options
can be employed.  For example, experiments have been  run in which price expectations are
formed using prior period price trajectories as a guide to forming expectations of future prices.
Similarly, experiments have been run in which model decision makers  were assumed to be
surprised by policy interventions. This flexibility allows experimentation with uncertainty
associated with expectation formation.
        When multiple ex post technologies are available, then a putty-semiputty relationship can emerge.
A putty-semiputty technology provides a lower elasticity1 of substitution in old capital than in new. In this
case, the choices of new capital provide greater flexibility in input substitution than does a particular type
of capital once it has been constructed.
        A putty-clay technology assumes that old capital is fixed-coefficient and the input-output
coefficients do not respond to price. The input-output coefficients reflect relative prices that were in effect
when the capital was new. Therefore, new capital is responsive to prices, but input-output coefficients are
locked into place  as the capital is converted from new to old. The elasticity of substitution between inputs
in a fixed-coefficient (or Lcontief) technology is zero.
        Some technologies are considered to be fixed-coefficient whether new or old, and are completely
unresponsive to prices. This technology is referred to as clay-clay or simply clay. This assumption is
sometimes used in the energy transformation sectors, especially oil refining, where the ratio of energy input
to energy output is fixed in advance by  physical processes and cannot respond to changes in price.
  The primary algorithm presently used to determine investment demand scales previous period
investment as shown:
            ,.   * i       ,    *  working  age   population,   .     .c
    xt,  = sclinv * base _ kap * - &-  f>  -r  r - /_ *£^y                   (22)
                              working _age _ population,^
where sclinv is a scalar multiplier, base_kap is investment in the previous period,
E(n) is expected profits per dollar of investment (normalized to one in the base period) and £ is an
accelerator (typically set at one).
A second options begins by computing  output expected from new capital as the difference between
expected future output for the sector and output from the existing capital stock:
             <7-4,0M                                                                  (23)
where q , is total expected output and  q M is output from old capital.  The demand for new capital is thus
computed as
    *,=»,(?)?,.„„ W                                                            (24)
where a(,{p) is a capital-output coefficient given by equation (7) and E(ftY is as in (22).
                                              IS

-------
Future price expectations are just that in the SGM, expectations.  Investors can make mistakes.
Market clearing prices in future periods may or may not fulfill prior expectations.  Though full
perfect foresight could in principle be enforced within the context of the SGM, this experiment
has never been run. Implementing this assumption requires that the basic model be wrapped in
software to enforce the consistency.  While there is no obvious obstruction to implementing a
perfect foresight version of the SGM, run times are typically significantly longer than for a
recursive model and sponsors of the model have never encouraged development along these lines.
Model development along other lines has held higher priority.

Whenever a production sector is split into subsectors, a method for allocating sector-level
investment across subsectors is  required.  The electricity sector operates somewhat differently
from the other producing sectors in that there are several generating technologies, or subsectors,
each with its own production function.  Each electric generating technology is represented by a
production function with a very  low elasticity of substitution.  Price response in the electricity
sector is governed mainly by a logit sharing process that controls investment rates in generating
technologies as the relative expected profit per kWh changes.  One advantage of this electricity
generation  structure is that it preserves energy balances: for any particular generating technology,
heat rates remain in a limited range with limited response to changes in fuel prices; output of the
sector is the sum of output by technology.

Investment is allocated to production activities in two stages, first to production sectors and then
to subsectors within a sector.  With the exception of the "everything else" sector, each separate
sector in the SGM represents production of a distinct product.  Subsectors represent different
ways  of making that product.  Presently, electricity generation is the only sector with more than
one subsector.

The allocation of investment to  new plant and equipment is not a "winner-take-all" decision.
Rather, the greater the expected profitability, the greater the share of investment allocated to the
investment. Once new capacity is added to the economy, its capital stock and production
function are fixed and remain in that state until retired.

The production of primary energy presents special issues that must be taken into account.  The
SGM distinguishes between resources and reserves of depletable energy resources: oil, natural
gas, and coal.  Energy reserves represent quantities of the resource that are known to exist and
which can be profitably produced at current prices. The production of oil, natural gas, and coal
all occur out of energy reserves. Reserves are generally adequate to provide continuous supply
for only a limited time. They are constantly being drawn down by production and  supplemented
by additions from resources. In principle, resources include all occurrences that could ever be
found and potentially produced  with any possible technology.  Thus, reserves are known with a
high degree of certainty while resources are known with much lower certainty. Resources can be
disaggregated into grades which partition by total cost of production. SGM 2004 has the
potential to disaggregate resources into any number of grades,  depending on the data.

At the beginning of any five-year time step, the SGM has a set of technology vintages for
producing energy from reserves. Like any produced good in the SGM, the production rate from
each vintage is limited by the historical capital stock. In addition, cumulative production is
limited by the reserves that are associated with that particular vintage.  The SGM augments that
production capability from resources.  Like other produced goods, the SGM has a set of available
technologies, described in the form of available production functions, which can be applied to
resources to produce new output. As the SGM brings a larger portion of the resource into the
                                            19

-------
reserve category, marginal cost rises. This in turn limits additions to reserves in any individual
period. Inter-time-step additions to capacity are inferred by extrapolation.

Technological Change in SGM

Technology can change from one period to the next. Technological change is exogenously
specified in the SGM.  That is, the relationship between inputs and outputs can be changed.
There is a multiplicity  of potential modes of change available in the SGM. These range from the
simplest, on-off types of change, to the enhancement or degradation of individual inputs to the
production process.  The "on-off' mode of change is simple. In this mode technology options
can either be made available—new options coming on line—or can be taken off line.  For
example, coal gasification combined cycle with CCh capture and geologic storage may be
unavailable prior to a specific  date when it is "turned on".  Similarly, a technology could be
"turned off"—made unavailable, for example as a consequence of a policy intervention such as a
technology performance  standard.

More common is technological change that incrementally  enhances the contribution of inputs to
the production process for new investments. For example the process for producing electricity
using coal could require one-half percent less of each input every year for 10 years with no
change after that.  This of course, would only apply to new vintages of the technology installed.
Alternatively, labor productivity may rise systematically from period to period.  Improvements in
labor productivity- for new vintages of capital are the primary determinants of economic growth
per capita in SGM.

Energy efficiency and  labor productivity are the two most important productivity parameters in
the SGM. Labor productivity  parameters are the primary determinant of economic growth in
SGM and are used to influence the time path of GDP in a reference case. These two sets of
parameters, energy efficiency  and labor productivity, assist in constructing reference or business-
as-usual scenarios. The labor  productivity parameters are used to determine a time path for GDP
and the energy efficiency parameters are used to determine consumption of energy by fuel and
therefore emissions.38
38       If the efficiency of all inputs to a given production process is changing at the same rate, then
technical change is said to be neutral. If the rate of change in efficiency varies across inputs, then technical
change is said to be non-neutral or biased. Neutral technical change in the SGM is represented by a
multiplicative parameter in each production function. This parameter increases the input efficiency of all
inputs by the same rate. The SGM can also represent non-neutral technical change.  For example, we could
have a technology for which labor productivity is improving at a faster rate than energy efficiency.  In this
case the amount of labor needed per unit of output is falling faster than the amount of energy needed per
unit of output.
        If the production process is fixed-coefficient, then these technical change parameters can be used
to precisely control input efficiency. However, most production processes are not fixed-coefficient, at least
in the long run as old capital is replaced by new capital. Most production processes respond to changes in
prices of inputs by substituting away from those inputs that are relatively expensive.  In this case, input
efficiency is affected by both the exogenous technical change parameters described in this section and by
changes in relative prices. Changes in input efficiency are a combination of exogenous technical change
and price-induced technical change.  Exogenous technical change is represented by a shifting isoquant;
price-induced technical change is represented by shifts along an isoquant.
        All of the a parameters in the CES production function, as well as the corresponding parameters in
fixed-coefficient production, can be specified to have a growth rate f during each of the SGM's five-year
time steps (NSTEP=5). This is similar to Autonomous Energy Efficiency Improvement (AEEI) used in
some other energy models; but in the SGM, exogenous rates of technical change can be specified for all
                                             20

-------
                    Households
4»
                    The left hand side of Figure 3.1 represents the final demands of the economy. The SGM treats
                    the household and government sectors in a simplified manner.  All of the revenues from taxes go
                    to the government sector.  All of the wages from labor, all of the returns to capital, all of the rents
                    on land, and all of the returns to mineral resources are income for the household sector.

                    The household sector makes decisions about demographics, labor supply, savings, and the
                    portfolio of final consumption.  SGM 2004 treats demographics, labor supply, and savings
                    simply. The demographic structure of the population is built up through assumptions about age-
                    and gender-specific fertility rates and survival rates39. This in turn implies a work-aged
                    population. The application of age- and gender-specific labor-force participation rates, which can
                    vary with time, yields a labor force for a model scenario. The supply of labor is assumed to be
                    positively related to the wage rate40.

                    inputs to production, not just energy. For example, the labor productivity parameter is used primarily for
                    calibrating the SGM to a GDP growth path.  The energy productivity parameters are then used to adjust
                    energy consumption. Technical change growth rates can either grow smoothly over time or vary between
                    time steps.
                            In this case all of the a, parameters within a production function are assumed to change at the
                    same rate under neutral technical change. This is equivalent to varying only Ob, as is shown in the
                    following equation.

                                                                          (19)
                    T is an integer that represents the model time period, where T=0 during the base year of 1 990.  Since the
                    model runs in five-year time steps, T=l represents 1995. If t is the number of years since 1990, then
                            t = T x NSTEP
                    Because neutral technical change over long periods of time can result in violation of physical laws
                    concerning rates of conversion of energy from one form to another, it is used onJy sparingly in the SGM.
                            Instead of adjusting «c to represent technical change, each of the a, parameters are adjusted with
                    their own technical change parameters y,.  Note that an increasing  a, represents improved technical
                    efficiency.
                                                                          (20)
                                         5=1
                            This is the preferred way to represent technical change in the SGM, as it allows for precise control
                    over physical conversion of energy from one form to another and thus ensures physical consistency, critical
                    in a model that seeks to understand physical climate process.
                    ^9
                      The SGM keeps track of population within each region by gender and five-year age cohort. Population
                    data may be read in directly, using projections from the World Bank, United Nations, or US Census Bureau
                    for the model base year and all future SGM time steps. This is the usual way of specifying population in
                    the SGM.  Alternatively, base-year population may evolve in the SGM by applying assumptions with
                    regard to survival rates, fertility rates, and migration rates. For any time period, total population is given by
POPtol =
POP
                                          agemales
                                                                                                            (33)
                                  age =4
                    where POPagfmiat, is the number of males in age group age; POP ag,jemaits is the number of females in age
                    group age~, and NAGE is the number of age groups defined.
                      Labor supply in the SGM is deri\red using the following equation.
             0 -
                                                                  !abar
                                                                                                            (34)
                                                                 21

-------
The supply of land is constrained by the total surface area and positively related to the rental rate
on land '.  In addition to the supply of land, there is also a demand for land by the household
sector.

The household sector is an important source of savings. The other major sources of savings are
retained corporate earnings and net government savings (or dissavings).  Savings is proportional
to income and positively related to the rate of interest42.

The demand for final goods and services by the household sector is determined by prices and
aggregate consumption43 in conjunction with price and income elasticities44.

Closing the System

Each regional representation of the  SGM needs to describe how its markets include trade with the
rest of the world. There are three options for each market: tradable, non-tradable, or traded at a
fixed quantity. When an individual region is solved independently of the rest of the world, a
fixed world price is assumed for certain tradable goods; regions may import or export as much of
that good as desired at that fixed world price, subject to an overall balance of payments
constraint.  For all non-tradable goods, the quantity of trade is fixed in advance.

One produced good is selected as the numeraire.  This is the "everything else"45 good and it is
tradable. The price of the  numeraire good is set to 1 during each time period. Except for the
where alabor is the maximum potential share of working age population employed in any given year;
POPwariuntfg, is the total working age population (ages 15 to 64); /JL.<»- is a labor supply responsiveness
coefficient; and Piai,or is the average annual wage rate.
   Households supply land, on the basis of a land rental rate, according to (he following equation.
                                      /»toM,))                                            (35)
where aiand is the maximum potential share ofland supplied to the market; LAND is the total land area that
could be managed for agricultural or other purposes; /?;„,„/ is a land supply responsiveness coefficient; and
Piand is the average annual rental rate on a unit of land.
   SGM represents savings as a function of present income and the interest rate,
                                        r))                                             (36)
where auum, is the maximum potential savings rate; Y is disposable personal income; £«„„», is a scale
parameter; /?«„,,„ determines the sensitivity of households to the interest rate; and r is the interest rate.
  The total value of consumption can then be calculated by
                     land, hh land ~ * labor ,hh  labor
M These demand functions are consistent with the existence of a utility function for the household sector
and the assumption of utility maximization, though this places important constraints on parameter values.
The functional relationships are given by

                                                                                        (41)

where Xd, AA is demand for good / by the household sector; a^h is the household demand intensity factor for
good !';/?,.«, is the price elasticity of demand by households for good i; yy,>, is the income elasticity of
demand by households for good ;'; and
         NS
            «a^'C-M-'                                                           (42)
                                              22

-------
Middle East, all regions are price takers with respect to oil and natural gas. Land and labor are
always non-tradable. All other sectors are either non-tradable or have the quantity of trade set in
advance.

An exogenous balance-of-payments constraint is specified in advance for each region. Most
regions are assumed to move linearly from a historical trade balance in the base year to balanced
trade sometime in the future.

With specification of a trading status for each market, the model has all of the information that it
needs to find a solution. The model is said to have solved when it has a set of prices for all goods
and services that allows all sellers of a good, service, or primary factor of production to sell as
much as they want at that set of prices and all buyers to be able to buy as much as they want at
that set of prices.  Furthermore, all economic agents, producers, households, and government
have exactly the income necessary to match their demands and supplies.  Obviously, the solution
algorithm uses non-linear methods to obtain the necessary solution prices. Nevertheless, the
system is sufficiently well behaved that finding a solution is not a problem46.

Global Model with Trade in Emissions Permits
The  global version of the SGM is used when there is at least one market that must clear globally.
For example, carbon emissions permits may be traded  among regions.  The model searches for a
global permit price that clears the market for permits.

Many of the SGM regions, including India and China,  operate in local currency. Therefore, an
exchange rate  must be selected to convert the  world market permit price, in U.S. dollars, into
local currency. The SGM uses base-year (1990) market exchange rates for this conversion.

The global model can be run with oil prices set exogenously. Given die difficulty of modeling
OPEC pricing behavior, most model exercises use a projected time path of oil prices provided by
others. In this case, all regions except the Middle East treat this price parametrically. The Middle
East then supplies whatever oil is needed to meet global demand.
Greenhouse Gas Emissions

As noted earlier there are multiple gases that are relevant to climate change. Non-CO2
greenhouse related gases are critical to understanding climate change and are accorded
commensurate importance in the SGM.  The SGM can be run to mitigate just CO2 or CO2 plus
the Kyoto "basket" of greenhouse gases—CH4, N2O, HFC's, PFC's and SF6. The SGM solves
the problem of the determining equivalencies between the different gases by using 100 year
global warming potentials47.
45 In regions which have been updated to include energy intensive sectors, transport and buildings,
"everything else" approximates the services sector. In less elaborate sectoral breakdowns it includes
everything not explicitly modeled.
46 In fact, failure of the system to solve is usually associated with a data input error.
'17 The global warming potential  (G WP) is the instantaneous radiative forcing that results from the addition
of one kilogram (kg) of a gas to the atmosphere, relative to that of one kg of carbon dioxide. They are
defined for a variety of integration time horizons.  The IPCC provides values for 20 years, 100 years, and
500 years. By selecting an integration time horizon, e.g. 100 years, GWP values can be used as a proxy to
compare the relative climate impacts of one kg of a set of greenhouse gases.
                                            23

-------
Given the wide variety emissions and technologies for controlling them, there are a variety of
mitigation options in the SGM. These options include 1) for €62 detailed modeling of the CCh
emissions response to a carbon price, 2) for non-CO* emissions the use of exogenous curves
relating percent reduction in emissions to the carbon price and 3) for soil and forest based
sequestration, the use of exogenous results showing the amount sequestered as a function of the
carbon price.

Investment and operating decisions respond to policy instruments. A carbon value can be
associated with the carbon content of fuels and in this case would affect the price paid  by
consumers of the fuel. This in turn would affect investment decisions and the purchase of inputs
to production processes. Carbon values can either be exogenously given or endogenously
determined, as for example in cap-and-trade regimes. The presence of vintaged capital and low
elasticity of substitution for existing capital stocks means that the fuil response to a carbon price
takes time to materialize (see figure 4.4). The  carbon price necessary to achieve a given  target is
a function not only of the target, but also of both the baseline trajectory and the portfolio of
technologies available for investment. The technology portfolio has, in addition to its  impact on
the carbon price, a significant impact on the balance between lowering emissions and lowering
energy use that is necessary to achieve the target.

For the non-COz emissions, as shown in Table 3.2, there are six gases and more than a dozen
sources, making the process modeling used for CO2 impractical.  Rather, the approach is to
determine emissions as a function of a base period emissions factor and  an activity level  and then
reduce these emissions as a function of the carbon price using exogenous process-based estimates
of the relationship between the carbon price and the percent reduction in emissions.  These
external estimates, called marginal abatement cost curves (M ACCs) are specific to each source
and emission.
                                           24

-------
                 Table 3.2: Emission Sources, Drivers and Control Options
   Activity
   Oil Combustion
   Gas Combustion
   Coal Combustion
   Coal Production
   Enteric
   NatGasSys
   OilSys
   Manure
   OthAgMeth
   ManureN
   SoilN
   Landfills
   OthNonAgMeth
   Wastewater
   HFC23
   ODSSub
   IndProcsN
   MobileN
   StationaryN
   Aluminum
   Semiconductor
   Mg
   ElecDist
   Soil and Forest
   Sequestration
(DeAngclo et a! 2004,
   Emission
   CO2
   CO,
   CO.
   CH4
   ca,
   en,
   ca,
   CH4
   CH4
   N,O
   N20
   CH4
   CH4
   CH4
   HFC-23
   HFC's
   N20
   N2O
   N,O
   PFC's
   PFC's
   SF6
   SF6

   C02
Delhotal et al 2004,
      Driver
      Total Combustion
      Total Combustion
      Total Combustion
      Coal
      Ag Production
      Gas Trans & Dist
      Oil Production
      Ag Production
      Ag Production
      Ag Production
      Ag Production
      Everything Else
      Everything Else
      Everything Else
      Everything Else
      Everything Else
      Every thing Else
      Everything Else
      Everything Else
      Everything Else
      Everything Else
      Everything Else
      Electricity
      NA

Schaefer et al 2004, Scheele
 Mitigation option
 Endogenous
 Endogenous
 Endogenous
 MAC
 MAC
 MAC
 MAC
 MAC
 MAC
 MAC
 MAC
 MAC
 MAC
 MAC
 MAC
 MAC
 MAC
 MAC
 MAC
 MAC
 MAC
 MAC
 MAC
 Sequestration
 function
and Krugcr, 2004)
The base period emissions factor is determined from the ratio of base period emissions to the base
period activity level (denoted as the driver in Table 3.2).  In addition to the cost curves and base
period emissions, there are model inputs which can be used to match the time path of emissions to
an external source. For the most recent analysis of the full set of greenhouse gases, Stanford
Energy Modeling Forum (EMF-21), we used the Environmental Protection Agency's estimates of
the emissions trajectories as well as their estimates of the reduction in emissions as the carbon
price increases.

The third major emissions mitigation strategy is soil and forest carbon sequestration. Here
through changes in management practices for crops and forest, carbon stores on the land can be
increased.  While we are working on making these sequestration options an endogenous part of
the model, this effort is not yet complete, so in the meantime we use an exogenous estimate from
Bruce McCarl48 of the amount of sequestration which will occur as a function of the carbon price.
 ! McCarl, personal communication oi'FASOM results.
                                         25

-------
                     IV. The SGM in Use: Data and Parameters

While the theoretical structure of the SGM can accommodate any number of regions and sectors,
the model as implemented has fourteen regions and varying numbers of sectors (10 to 24).
Regions for which an operating SGM model version exists are given in Table 4.1. Each regional
SGM is instantiated using the same generic procedures. The model is first calibrated so that it
reproduces  a base year, presently 1990.

Model Calibration and Initialization

Model calibration and initialization requires three different types of data:

    1.      Economic and Demographic Data
    2.      Energy Balances, and
    3.      Technology Descriptions.

Economic data include input-output tables and supplemental information from the national
income accounts as well as energy balance tables obtained either from the International Energy
Agency (IEA) or from government agencies within a region.

	Table 4.1. Regions in the SGM	
Annex I
Non-Annex I
United States
Canada
Western Europe
Japan
Australia and New Zealand
Former Soviet Union
Eastern Europe	
China
India
Brazil
Mexico
South Korea
Middle East
Rest of World
Most input data require some form of processing before being used in the SGM. When
constructing a new SGM region, or updating an existing region to a new base year, the majority
of time is spent obtaining and processing the necessary data.  Usually, available data will not
exactly match SGM requirements  and modeler's judgment is often needed to reconcile
differences. This is especially true for multi-country regions.
                          Table 4.2. Data Transformation in SGM
Original Data
1990 Economic Input-Output Table
1990 Energy Balance Table
Annual Investment Data by Sector
Data on Fossil Fuel Resources
Electricity Supply: generation, installed
capacity, energy consumption, capital costs,
operating costs
National Income Accounts
Derived Data for SGM
Hybrid Input-Output Table
Capital Stocks by Sector
Resource Grades
Input-output representation of
electricity generation by fuel
Tax rates, Savings rates
                                          26

-------
Input-Output Tables

The most important data set to be collected is a base-year input-output table of the economy.
This forms the basic economic framework that all of the other data conform to.

Traditional economic input-output tables provide an economic framework for constructing a CGE
model. However, input-output tables use currency units that might not convert consistently to
physical units such as energy-. We supplement the economic data from an input-output table with
an energy  balance table, which is essentially an energy input-output table. The resulting hybrid
input-output table has energy units (joules) for energy carriers and currency units for all other
goods. Such a table allows exact base-year model calibration to base-year energy balances and
ensures that energy balance is maintained throughout all model time periods.  This also facilitates
base-year calibration of carbon emissions, as most carbon emissions are the result of energy
combustion. The concept of a hybrid energy input-output table is described in Miller and Blair
(1985).

Economic Input-Output Tables

We have obtained input-output tables for the United States, Canada, Japan, China, India, Mexico,
and South Korea. However, these are generally produced at five-year intervals and may not be
available for the SGM base year of 1990.  For example, input-output tables for the United States
are available for 1987 and 1992.  A 1990 input-output table for the United States was constructed
through interpolation and the use of other economic data.

Multi-country regions present a particular challenge because input-output tables are not available
for all countries in the region, and each country has its own currency.  It may be necessary to
build an input-output table based on data from the national income accounts and from patterns in
other input-output tables. For single-country regions, the units are local currency, such as Korean
won or Indian rupees.  United States dollars are used as a common currency for multi-country
regions.

An economic input-output table has three major sections: interindustry flows, value added, and
final demand.  An input-output table is organized with inputs as rows and activities as columns as
shown in Figure 4.3. Inputs include intermediate inputs (those derived from a production
process) and primary factors of production.  The primary factors of production are labor, capital,
and sometimes land. Activities that use inputs are industries, consumption by consumers,
consumption by  government, investment, and net exports (exports minus  imports).
                                           27

-------
                           Figure 4.1. Typical Input-Output Table

                                production activities            C G  I  X  M
              intermediate
              inputs
                                 interindustry flows
              primary
              factors
value added
An economic input-output table is a snapshot of an economy, in value terms, for one particular
year.  Input-output tables contain varying amounts of sectoral detail, depending on the country,
with anywhere from 30 to over 500 producing sectors. The tables arc aggregated to the level of
detail that best matches the structure of SGM. Usually, an input-output table contains the same
number of producing sectors as there are intermediate inputs. This does not have to be the case,
however, because some industries may produce more than one product and some inputs might not
be produced domestically and must be imported.

Oil and natural gas present a special problem because they are often treated as a joint product
from a single industry.  Almost all input-output  tables consider oil and natural gas production to
be a single industry producing a single composite product. This is one area in which energy
balance tables provide essential information to maintain a clear distinction between oil and
natural gas production and consumption.

Energy Balance Input-Output Tables

Since the SGM is an energy model as well as an economic model, attention is paid to maintaining
energy balances as the model operates through time. An energy balance table is used for base-
year calibration of energy production and consumption.  An energy balance table is essentially an
energy input-output table in physical units. The original units might be tons of coal equivalent
(China), tons of oil equivalent (1EA statistics), or calories (Japan).  In the SGM, we convert all
energy units to joules, expressed as either petajoules (PJ) or exajoules (EJ).  The format of a
typical energy balance table is shown in Figure  4.2.  Note that the role of rows  and columns is
transposed relative to an economic input-output table: the columns contain energy inputs while
the rows contain energy consumption activities.
                                           28

-------
                          Figure 4.2. Typical Energy Balance Table

                                             energy inputs (fuels)
                  production
                  imports
                  exports

                  electricity generation
                  oil refining
                  coking
                  agriculture
                  industry
                  transport
                  residential buildings
                  commercial buildings
      sources
energy transformation
  final consumption
The IIEA compiles annual energy balance tables for both OECD and non-OECD countries. IEA
energy balances provide a consistent energy balance table format across countries. Energy
balance tables may be summed across countries to form an energy balance table for a multi-
country region.  However, the IEA energy balance tables are not as detailed as may be obtained
through local governments.  The SGM uses IEA energy balances for all of the multi-country
SGM regions, but uses local energy data for all of the single-country regions (United States,
Canada, Japan, China, India, Mexico, South Korea, and Brazil).

The following steps are used to create a hybrid input-output table from an economic input-output
table and energy balance table.

    1. Put the economic  input-output table in a format suitable for SGM. This involves
    aggregation across producing sectors and possible conversion to a 1990 base year.

    2. Obtain 1990 energy balance table and convert units to joules.

    3. Aggregate energy balance table across fuels to match SGM format.

    4. Rearrange activities (rows) within the energy balance table to match those of the economic
    input-output table.

    5. Transpose the energy balance table so that rows correspond to fuel inputs and columns
    correspond to energy-consuming activities.

    6. Create a hybrid input-output table where the energy rows (inputs) come from the
    transposed energy balance table and all other rows come from the economic input output-
    table. This table is no longer in value terms but is now considered to be in quantity terms
    with units of joules for the energy rows and units of 1990 dollars (or other local currency) for
    all other rows.
                                           29

-------
    7. Find a set of prices for all intermediate inputs that will "rebalance" the hybrid input-output
    table in value terms. By rebalancing, we mean that the value of output in each producing
    sector is equal to the total value of inputs.  A linear equation may be derived for each
    producing sector, resulting in a system of equations that can be solved to obtain a price for
    each intermediate input. These linear equations are sometimes referred to as "zero-profit
    conditions". It is important to note that these prices are derived from the calibration process
    and are not historical prices. This reflects our modeling philosophy that assumed technology
    characteristics, represented by the input-output and energy balance data, should determine
    relative prices in the model, and not the other way around. Finally, create a new hybrid
    input-output table in value terms by multiplying all quantities by their respective prices.

    8. We have the option of redefining units for the non-energy inputs in the hybrid input-output
    table. We usually redefine these units so that prices equal 1.0 in the base year, but energy
    prices can remain in terms of dollars (or other local currency) per gigajoule.

The final hybrid input-output table provides us with a representation of the economy that is
completely consistent with base-year  energy' balances.  Energy production and consumption for
each fuel will exactly match the quantities in the base-year energy balance table.

Investment Data and Capital Stocks

The SGM operates in five-year time steps and keeps track of capital stocks in five-year vintages.
At the end of each SGM time period,  the model converts investment for each producing sector
into a capital stock, with the capital stock defined to be five year's worth of investment. Each
type of capital stock has a data-input specified lifetime, typically four time periods or 20 years.
At the end of the capital stock lifetime, the capital is retired and no longer used.  Capital stocks
are operated across their lifetime with no decrease in technical efficiency.

Calibration of the SGM requires that we determine the quantities of capital needed for all
producing sectors by vintage. For example, using a 1990 base year and a capital lifetime of 20
years, we would need four capital stocks which equal investment during the  time periods 1971-
1975, 1976-1980,1981-1985, and 1986-1990. The following steps are used to create capital
stocks for a region.

    1. Obtain historical time scries of investment data for each producing sector.

    2. Fit an exponential curve to the  investment data for each producing sector. This provides a
    way to smooth out  the effects of recessions or other temporary deviations from a long-term
    trend. This also provides a way to extrapolate data backwards in time if the historical time
    series of investment is not long enough to create all of the needed capital stocks.

    3. Convert investment data to real 1990 currency (e.g., 1990 U.S. dollars) using a time series
    of GDP deflators.

    4. Sum investment  by sector across each five-year time period to create  capital stocks with
    units of 1990 currency.

Figure 4.3 provides an  example of annual investment data available for papermaking and paper
products sector in China. An exponential line is fit to the historical data for  China to smooth out
the effects of a recession around 1990. The exponential fit also allows us to extrapolate
                                            30

-------
investment data backwards to before 1980 when annual investment data by sector is not available.
The smoothed data are summed over five-year intervals to create capital stock vintages.
           Figure 4.3. Annual Investment: Paper Making and Paper Products in China
                      50-


                      45-


                      40
                      35
           100 million yuan,
            (1990 yuan)  '
                       1980
                                                           x   •
                               1982
                                      1984
                                              1986
                                                      1988
                                                             1990
                                                                     1992
                                                                             1994
Production Functions

Each column (excluding final demand) in the hybrid input-output table provides a representation
of the inputs to a production process.  For each input, there is an associated price and quantity.
All production processes are assumed to be constant-returns-to-scale, implying the rate of
conversion of inputs to output is independent of scale."9

For calibration of production functions, we model a hypothetical plant with some given output
capacity.  For example,  we could choose  to represent coal-fired electric power generating plants
as having a capacity of 500 megawatts.

Physical input-output coefficients can be  derived from the hybrid input-output table for each
combination of input and production process. The quantity of output is found by dividing the
value of output by its price. Similarly, the quantity of input is found by dividing the value of
input by its price.  The input-output coefficient is then the quantity of input divided by the
quantity of output.

It is important to remember that the technical coefficients of an economic production function are
not the same as the input-output coefficients.  In the special case of fixed-coefficient production,
49 The energy supply sectors, however, do not exhibit constant returns to scale. In energy supply, the cost
of production increases due to declining qualify of the energy resources as they are consumed. The
resource constraint implies decreasing returns to scale for primary energy supplies.
                                            31

-------
the technical coefficients of the production function are related to input-output coefficients in a
direct way that is independent of price50.

In general, input-output coefficients are related to the technical coefficients of production
functions through prices. If the relative price of an input to production rises, the derived demand
for that input will fall.  The rate at which one input is substituted for another, relative to the rate
of change in prices of those inputs, is referred to as the elasticity of substitution among inputs to
production.  In a constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) production function; this elasticity of
substitution  remains constant across changes in price (hence the name of the production function).
Equation (7) shows the dependence of input-output coefficients on CES technical coefficients,
relative prices, and the  assumed elasticity of substitution. In the SGM calibration process, we
invert this relationship  and solve for technical coefficients as a function of input-output
coefficients, prices, and the elasticity of substitution.

As the SGM searches for equilibrium prices, technical coefficients remain invariant with respect
to price.  However, input-output coefficients respond to changes in price.  The rate of response,
governed by the elasticity of substitution, is important for climate policy.  Real world production
processes will respond  to changes in the price of fossil fuels and the SGM reflects this behavior.
There are also physical limits to the degree of substitution.  For example, power plant efficiencies
cannot exceed limits imposed by the second law of thermodynamics and for some technologies
responsiveness is even  more tightly constrained. Note that the input-output table tells us nothing
about die elasticity of substitution among inputs in production.  That parameter must be set
exogenously using published results from econometric studies, simulations of bottom-up
technology models, or expert judgment.
Elasticities

Table 4.3 provides a list of typical elasticities of substitution (for producers) and demand
elasticities (for consumers).  Short-run elasticities of substitution are kept small, between
0.00 and 0.10 for all producing sectors. This means that previously constructed capital
has limited ability to respond to changing relative prices
 1 This is discussed in detail in the technical annex to SGM documentation.
                                            32

-------
Table 4.3. Typical Producer and Consumer Elasticities in the Second Generation Model
Production activity/ Long-run Short-run
consumption good elasticity of elasticity of
substitution for substitution for
producers producers
Agriculture
Services
Crude Oil
Natural Gas
Coal
Coke
Electricity
Refined Petroleum
Distributed Gas
Paper and Pulp
Chemicals
Non-metallic
minerals
Primary Metals
Food Processing
Other Industry
Passenger Transport
Freight Transport
0.30
0.40
0.28
0.28
0.28
0.28
0.10
0.10
0.10
0.28
0.28
0.28

0.28
0.28
0.28
0.28
0.28
0.10
0.10
0.10
0.10
0.10
0.10
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.10
0.10
0.10

0.10
0.10
0.10
0.10
0.10
Own-price Income elasticity
elasticity of of demand for
demand for consumers
consumers
-0.38
-1.02


-0.21

-0.21
-0.21
-0.21
-1.02
-1.02
-1.02

-1.02
-1.02
-1.02
-1.02
-1.02
0.32
1.01


0.50

0.50
0.50
0.50
1.01
1.01
1.01

1.01
1.01
1.01
1.01
1.01
Elasticities were set using expert judgment after surveying the open literature. The range of
estimates for price elasticities of demand for energy is documented in Edmonds (1978) updated
and summarized in Edmonds and Reilly (1985) as well as Bohi (1981) and numerous individual
studies51,

The Baseline Scenario

The first step in constructing a baseline scenario is calibration of the SGM to a base year as
discussed above. The next step is to introduce values for future exogenous variables such as
demographics, technology, and factor productivity trends. There are occasions when it is
desirable for the SGM baseline behavior to mimic that of some externally specified profile over
some period into the future. For example, the SGM-USA has on various occasions been asked to
create a baseline scenario that is consistent with that of the Annual Energy Outlook, published by
the U.S. Energy Information Administration,  hi practice, we have found a sequential process
works best in creating a baseline scenario consistent with an externally specified trajectory. This
process begins by  matching labor force assumptions, proceeds to then match next gross domestic
product (GDP)52 paths, then moves on to electricity generation, and finally  fossil fuel
consumption.

Various technical parameters are available in SGM to influence the time path of model output,
especially  autonomous time trends governing the efficiency of inputs in production processes. In
matching a baseline scenario to a desired GDP path we use an exogenous estimate of the labor
force and then  adjust an autonomous labor efficiency improvement parameter to get the desired
Sl A forthcoming study from Resources For the Future, sponsored by the Economic Analysis Branch, will
update these values.
^2 Since the SGM is a CGE model, the GDP is an output rather than an input to the model.
                                           33

-------
aggregate output level.  The second step is to match projections of electricity generation, in units
of billion kilowatt-hours, by adjusting an autonomous electricity efficiency improvement
parameter in all model activities that use electricity.  Third, the mix of fossil fuels within
electricity generation is adjusted by varying the time path of the cost to produce electricity using
oil, natural gas, or coal.  Fourth, fossil fuel consumption outside of electricity generation is
adjusted using fossil fuel efficiency improvement parameters in all model activities that use fossil
fuels. These adjustments in efficiency and cost parameters are not independent, so the baseline
calibration process is repeated at least once. The choice of baseline has significant impacts on
estimated costs to be emissions targets and thus being able to emulate a standard baseline is
important when participating in multi-model exercises such as the Stanford EMF.

Response to Carbon Prices

An important summary of the behavior of a model in terms of greenhouse gas abatement is the
marginal abatement cost curve (MACC). A MACC maps the relationship between the cost of
emitting the gas and the reduction in emissions relative to the reference case. Clearly, each
MACC is a contingent mapping derived under ceteris paribus conditions. In contrast to the non-
CO2 gases, where the SGM uses exogenous estimates of the MACC to determine the impact of
an inclusive carbon management policy, the SGM internally estimates the response of carbon
emissions to a carbon price. Using a number of model runs, a MACC for carbon emissions can
then be created and used, for example, in simple desk top systems to investigate the impact of
various carbon policies.

Several key elasticities help determine the response of carbon emissions to changes in energy and
carbon prices. Economic theory would suggest that the longer a price change is in effect, the
greater the response.  The SGM response to carbon prices exhibits precisely this behavior.
Elasticities of substitution for existing vintages of capital stock are relatively small, between 0.00
and 0.10 for all producing sectors, limiting short-term response within existing capital.  Over
time, new plant and equipment  becomes an increasingly important component of the economy.
As discussed earlier, substitution opportunities are greater for new investments as a greater array
of technology options are available.  Thus, the responsiveness of the carbon emissions to an
initial change in the price of emissions increases with the passage  of time.

This behavior is displayed in Figure 4.4.  This MACC's in the figure were constructed by
applying carbon values of ($10, $20, $30, $40, $50, $100, $150} in SGM-USA starting in the
2005 SGM time step and held constant thereafter.  The "start" curve in Figure 4.4 is the reduction
from baseline carbon emissions, expressed as  a percentage reduction, in the beginning time step
of 2005.  The other marginal abatement cost curves move out to the right as new capital stocks
adjust to the new set of relative prices after introduction of a carbon price. Carbon values in
Figure 4.4 are reported in 1990 U.S. dollars53.

MACCs constructed in  this way are also useful for reduced-form analysis of various permit
trading systems.  They can be combined with  MACCs from other  countries, MACCs for non-COa
greenhouse gases, and MACCs for mitigation opportunities in agriculture and forests.
53 A rough conversion to 2000 U.S. dollars can be made by multiplying all carbon prices by 1.25.
                                           34

-------
           180

           160-

           140 •

           120-
        -8 ioo
           80

           60

           40

           20
1
                                   start      +5 years  +10 years
             04"
             0%
                                                              long ran
                         5%
                                   10%        15%        20%
                                   Reduction from Baseline Emissions
                                                                     25%
                                                                                30%
 Figure 4.4. Marginal abatement cost curves for the United States energy system generated with a
                         series of constant-carbon-price experiments.
These marginal abatement cost schedules for SGM-2004 are significantly less elastic than SGM-
98. This is shown in Figure 4.5. Note that the MACCs derived from EMF runs are not the same

           Cost of U.S. Carbon Emission Reductions,
                                   2010
     $450


     $400


     $350
  $  $300
  ][  $250


  C  $200


  g  $150 •


     $100 •


     $50


      $-
       ft  GTEM
     -  # - - Merge3
     -•*- EPPA
     -"v— G-Cgbed
       •:-  AIM
     —•—CETA
     —«—-MS-MRT
     - -»- • OXEMOD
     •—3—RICE
     —•*•—WorMScan
     •• «•• SGM-98
     —fr—SGM-2004 (10-year response)
     ••••*•—SGM-2004 (5-year response)
         ^SGM-2004 (Long-term response)
                  •/> Reduction In Carbon Emissions compared to Reference
     Figure 4.5: Marginal Abatement Cost Curves (MACCs) in EMF-16 including SGM-98
 Compared with SGM-2004 Instantaneous, ten year, and Long-term Responses to Carbon Values
                                            35

-------
straightforward ceteris paribus calculation which varies price and nothing else.  Rather the EMF
calculations are dynamic with multiple factors varying simultaneously. Thus, while indicative of
behavior, they are not truly MACCs.

Figure 4.5 shows US carbon reduction MACCs for models that participated in the EMF-16
exercise, including SGM-98 (Weyant, 1999). These results are contrasted to the results from
SGM-2004. Three response periods are shown, five-year, ten-year, and long-term.  The five-year
response plots the percentage reduction relative to a reference case when a specific  value of
carbon is phased in over five years. The ten-year response case shows the percentage reduction
in carbon emissions relative to a reference case when die value of carbon  remains in place for
another five years. The long-term response shows the percentage reduction in carbon emissions
relative to a reference case when the value of carbon remains in place indefinitely.  The 2010
MACCs in EMF-16 represent a case in which carbon values had  existed for 10 years. The lower
elasticity of response in SGM  2004 is a direct reflection of the change in the treatment of vintages
in the SGM 2004.  Existing vintages of capital have relatively little latitude to respond to carbon
values in SGM 2004, whereas the assumed flexibility of existing plant and equipment was
significantly greater in SGM 9854.

Figures 4.6 and 4.7 show the results for the most recent EMF study, EMF-21. While the EMF-21
study focused on the combined suite of greenhouse gases, the available results do not permit
showing the impact of adding  the non-CO2 and forestry mitigation options, which is to
substantially reduce the marginal cost of reducing emissions. EMF-21, unlike EMF-16, did not
require modelers to use  a common reference case.  Since cost curves are driven by the target, the
reference case, and the set of management options, direct comparison between figures 4.5,4.6
and 4.7 is not possible.  Relative positions within Figure 4.5 are valid, but within 4.6 and 4.7 they
are complicated by differences in the base case.  In Figure 4.6, the SGM appears expensive, but it
has nearly a gigatonne higher  emissions in the base case than any other model. What is important
to note is the wide spread in costs.
54 The marginal value of a ton of carbon is the most comparable measure of cost across models. It is not
the only measure. At least two measures of cost are available from the SGM and from other models as
well. The first measure, which we call the direct cost, can be thought of as either a deadweight loss or the
integral under the marginal abatement curve for carbon. Either way, direct cost can be approximately equal
to one-half of the carbon price times the reduction in carbon emissions.  For international trade in carbon
emissions permits, direct costs are then adjusted by the value of transfer payments required to purchase or
sell permits.  This measure of net covst is simple to construct and is comparable across models.
        Of ultimate interest, however, is the net impact on some broader measure of economic activity
(such as GDP) or on economic welfare (such as real consumption). There are many reasons why the
change in GDP (or real consumption) is different from the direct cost net of transfer payments. These other
components of cost include the effects  of pre-existing fiscal distortions, changes in terms of trade, and the
ultimate disposition of government revenues.  In addition, measurement of GDP (or real consumption)
depends on the choice of index and base year used to construct that index. This reflects real-world
problems in constructing a quantity index for GDP when relative prices are changing.  The SGM reports
GDP as a quantity index of net output, with base-year (1990) prices as weights.
                                             36

-------
             EMF-21 USA Mitigtation Supply Schedule
         0%        10%       20%       30%       40%       50%      60%
             Percentage Reduction In Fossil Fuel Carbon Emissions Relative to the
                                   Reference Case
Figure 4.6 EMF 21 Marginal abatement cost curves for carbon for the United States
                 EMF-21 Global Mitigation Supply
   u
   •5
-•—AIM
••«	AMIGA
--*•-  COMBAT
 •••  EDGE
•-*	FUND
•-*— GEMINI-E3
	GRAPE
—	GTEM
    IMAGE
-*••• IPAC
 "MERGE
 ,:.  MESSAGE
 •  MiniCAM
   -SGM
   -WIAGI
                   10%
                            20%
                                     30%
                                              40%
                                                        50%
                                                                 60%
             Percentage Reduction in Fossil Fuel Carbon Emissions Relative to
                               the Reference Case
Figure 4.7 EMF 21 global marginal abatement cost curves.
                                        37

-------
                             V. Future Model Development

SGM 2004 is a benchmark version of the SGM. But, it is hardly the final version of the model.
The SGM has evolved substantially over the period of its existence.  It has remained a model
designed to address the climate change issue on a time scale consistent with the transition of
technology, looking forward five to fifty years.  The model structure was developed to explicitly
represent key features of the energy-economy-greenhouse-gas-emissions problem.  In that sense it
has remained true to its roots.  The model has evolved significantly over time adding richness and
detail in the process. Future model development is intended to continue that trend.

Perhaps the most important model development activity is the transformation of the SGM from a
model coded in FORTRAN to one coded in C++.  While this change in computational
environment may seem arcane, it has important implications for future model development. The
C++ environment means that most future changes to the model structure, e.g. the addition of
technology options or new inputs and outputs, will no longer require receding the model.  Rather,
such changes can be accomplished through changes in the database alone, thus accelerating the
rate of model development and decreasing the potential for errors. In a C++ environment, for
example, the introduction of a hydrogen market would be accomplished by simply changing the
database to include hydrogen.  Of course, making  model expansion simpler and less error-prone
doesn't solve the ongoing problem of data availability and quality.  No model is immune from the
problem of garbage-in-garbage-out.

Other areas in which model development is continuing include:  the household sector, investment
choice, expanded technology representations particularly in power generation, transportation,
buildings, and manufacturing, fossil fuel supply, agriculture-land-use, and the implementation of
nested CES production functions.  Much of this development will take advantage of knowledge
gained implementing these innovations in the simpler MiniCAM long-term analytical framework.

A high priority is the development of a more theoretically satisfying demand system for the
household sector that would allow for a consistent treatment of the consumption, savings, and
labor supply.  Incorporating consumption, savings and labor supply into a utility function
framework would allow calculation of welfare measures such as equivalent variation. This
having been said, the form of the household sector model remains to be determined. Given the
intergenerational nature of the time scale of the problem, an overlapping-generations model is a
candidate framework in addition to a single, infinitely-lived household model.

At the same time, the SGM team continues to maintain its international collaborations. The
Mexican module is being updated in collaboration with the Mexican Petroleum Institute (IMP).
The Japan module is being updated in collaboration with the National Institutes for
Environmental Studies (NIES) in Japan. A Germany module is under development with the
German Institute for Economic Research (DIW).  At the same time the SGM existing
collaborations are being continued with China, India, France, Korea, and Brazil.
                                  VII. REFERENCES

Bohi, D.R. (1981). Analyzing Demand Behavior:  A Study of Energy Elasticities, Johns Hopkins
University Press. Baltimore, MD.
                                           38

-------
Bush, G W. (2002), President Bush Announces Clear Skies and Global Climate Change
Initiatives, http://www.whitehouse.gov/news/releases/2002/02/20020214-5.html, accessed
10/13/04,2002

Christensen, L.R., D.W. Jorgenson and L.J. Lau (1971), "Conjugate Duality and the
Transcendental Logarithmic Production Function," Econometrica39, 255-256.

DeAngelo, B. J., DelaChesnaye, F. C., Beach, R. H., Sommer, A. and Murray, B. C. (2004).
"Methane and Nitrous Oxide Mitigation in Agriculture," Energy Journal (forthcoming).

DeCanio, S.  J. and J. A. Laitner.  (1997). Modeling Technological Change in Energy Demand
Forecasting:  A Generalized Approach. Technological Forecasting and Social Change. 55:249-
263.

Delholal, K.  C., DelaChesnaye, F. C., Gardiner, A., Bates, J. and Sankovski, A. (2004).
"Mitigation of Methane and Nitrous Oxide Emissions from Waste, Energy and Industry," Energy
Journal (forthcoming).

Dicwert,  W.E. (1971), "An Application of the Shephard Duality Theorem: A Generalized Leontief
Production Function," Journal of Political Economy 79, 481-507.

Edmonds, J.A. (1978).  A Guide to Price Elasticities of Demand for Energy: Studies and
Methodologies.  ORAU/IEA-78-04(M).

Edmonds, J.A., H.M. Pitcher, D.  Barns, R. Baron and M.A. Wise.  (1993). "Modeling Future
Greenhouse  Gas Emissions: The  Second Generation Model Description," in Modelling Global
Change, Lawrence R. Klein and Fu-chen Lo, eds. United Nations University Press, New York.

Edmonds, J. and Reilly, J. (1983). "A Long-Term, Global, Energy-Economic Model of Carbon
Dioxide Release from Fossil Fuel Use." Energy Economics, 5(2):74-88.

Edmonds, J. and Reilly, J. (1985). Global Energy:  Assessing the Future, Oxford University
Press, New York, pp.317.

Edmonds, J.A. and D.B. Reister.  (1982). "Characteristics of Nested CES Functions,"
IEA/ORAU-82-5-(M).

Edmonds, J. A. and J. Moreira (2003), Cross Cutting Theme: Technology in AR4,
bJdPJ£d\>^l^ipc^.cih£actwUl:lccL7^df,  accessed 10/13/04.

EIA (Energy Information Administration). (2000).  Emissions of Greenhouse Gases in the
United States 2000. Rcport#:DOE/EIA-0573(2000).

Hafcle. W.  (1981). Energy in a Finite World. Ballinger Publishing Company, Cambridge MA.

IPCC (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change),  (2001).  Climate Change 2001:  The
Scientific Basis. The Contribution of Working Group I to the Third Assessment Report of the
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. J. T. Houghton, Y. Ding, D,J. Griggs, M. Noguer, P.
J. van der Linden and D. Xiaosu (Eds.). Cambridge  University  Press, Cambridge, UK. pp 944.
                                          39

-------
Kheshgi, H., Smith, S.J., and Edmonds, J. (2003). "Emissions and Atmospheric CO2
Stabilization: Long-term Limits and Paths," accepted for publication in Mitigation and
Adaptation Strategies for Global Change, Climate Change and Environmental Policy.

McCarl, B., (2004), personal communication of FASOM model results, mccarl;g;tanm.edu.

Miller, R. E., and P. D. Blair. 1985. Input-Output Analysis: Foundations and Extensions.
Prentice-Hall, Inc., Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey.

Perroni, C. and T. F. Rutherford. 1998.  "A Comparison of the Performance of Flexible
Functional Forms for Use in Applied General Equilibrium Modelling." Computational
Economics, 11 (3): 245-263.

Perroni, C. and T.F. Rutherford. 1995. "Regular Flexibility of Nested CES Functions," European
Economic Review 39, 335-343.

S. 139 2003. Climate Stewardship Act of 2003.  115th Congress,  First Session. Sponsors:
McCain and Lieberman, Introduced 01/09/2003.

Schaefer, D. O., Godwin, D. and Harnisch, J.  (2004). "Estimating Future Emissions and Potential
Reductions of HFCs, PFCs and SF6," Energy Journal (forthcoming).

Scheele, E. A. and Kruger, D. (2004). "Global Anthropogenic Methane and Nitrous Oxide
Emissions,"  Energy Journal (forthcoming).

United Nations. 1997. Kyoto Protocol To The United Nations Framework Convention On
Climate Change. United Nations, New York.

Uzawa, H. (1962) "Production Functions with Constant Elasticity of Substitution," Review of
Economic Studies 30, 291-299.

Weyant, J.P. and J.N. Hill.  1999. ''Introduction and Overview,"  The Energy Journal, Special
Issue :vii-xliv.

Wigley, T.M.L., R. Richels & J. A. Edmonds. 1996. "Economic and Environmental Choices in
the Stabilization of Atmospheric CO2 Concentrations," Nature. 379(6562) :240-243.
                                          40

-------