FINAL REPORT                                                           JUNE 15,1971
                    URBAN AIR POLLUTION DAMAGE FUNCTIONS:
                           THEORY AND MEASUREMENT
                         A Report On The Statistical Association
                         Between Air Pollution And Single Family
                      Residential Property Values in Chicago, Illinois
                                     Prepared For
                           Environmental Protection Agency
                                Office of Air Programs
                                         By

                                   Thomas D. Crocker

-------
                    Urban Air Pollution Damage Functions:
                           Theory and Measurement*

                                      by

                              Thomas D. Crocker
                           Department of Economics
                     University of California, Rivexside
     *This paper is the final report for Research Contract CPA 22-69-52 of
the National Air Pollution Control Administration with the Regents of the

-------
                                  PREFACE





      Doctors,  lawyers,  merchants,  and  chiefs all.suspect  that  air pollution


 is unhealthy and damaging and  that something should be done about it.


      Unfortunately,  the exact  extent of the damages due to polluted  air
                             I                  *

 has not been determined.   Consequently, economic  evaluations of  damages


;have been more in the nature of informed guesses  than anything else.


      Until the doctors and ethers  have more definitive information,


 considerable reliance will have to be  placed on multivariate statistical


 analyses.  Ideally,  such studies would be  able to draw on consistent and


 reliable data over a long enough period of time  to allow  for study of


 time lags in the pollution-damage  relationship.


      This study by Professor Crocker is an important step in the direction


 of establishing a statistically significant inverse relationship between


 levels of air pollution and residential property values in the City  of


 Chicago.  Hopefully, investigators will recognize the problems and


 opportunities inherent in the  methodology. Perhaps, they can  both im-


 prove on the methodology and apply it  to even better data.  The  fact that


 Professor Crocker did, on the  basis of multivariate analysis,  find sta-


 tistical significance between  elevated pollution levels and depressed

           i
 property values comes as no surprise.  What is impressive is the manner


 and thoroughness with which the analyjjis^has proceeded.
Ji
                                                   -~{i ,
                                        Paul H.  Gerhardt
                                        Chief Economist
                                        Office of Program Development
                                        Air Pollution Control Office

-------
                        Acknowl ed g emen t s




     Several people have devoted extensive time and effort to




putting together the data employed in this study.  Foremost among




these is Mr. Rudi Winzinger, whose imaginativeness, understanding of




the econaaic form of the problem being studied, and attention to




tedious detail were mainly responsible for putting the data in a




form suitable for empirical analysis.  In a completely nontrivial




sense, he is responsible with the principal investigator for




whatever merit the empirical results may have.




     Mr. William F. Shaw, Chief of the Statistics Section of the




FHA's Division of Research and Statistics made the FHA data




available to the project.  His friendly and generous cooperation




and assistance is most gratefully acknowledged.  Paul Tsao of the




University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee's Social Science Research Center




devoted many long hours to the writing of programs for compiling




the data and performing the empirical analysis.  R. J. Anderson,




Jr. of Purdue University provided encouragement and assistance in




the project's initial stages.




     The author and the paper have benefited from an association




with the Program in Environmental Economics of the University of




California, Riverside.




     Mr. Paul Gerhardt and Mr. Brian Peckham have been the project




officers.  In many respects, the study's initial conception was




Mr. Gerhardt's.  Both gentlemen have always made the study a welcome





-------
                                ii
                            ABSTRACT




     This study is an extension of previous work done by the




present author and others on the covariation between air pollution




dosages and property values.  Data employed consist of the structural,




site, purchaser, sale, and neighborhood characteristics for each




of,1,288 FHA-insured single family residential property transactions




in Chicago, Illinois, from 1964 through 1967.  Arithmetic mean




dosages of suspended particulates and sulfur dioxide for each of




the forty-eight months in this period were calculated for each




transaction's location from basic point measurements.  The analysis




of this data served two purposes:  (1)  the testing of new economic




hypotheses about the relation between property values and air




pollution; and (2)  to remove possible sources of statistical bias




present in previous studies.




     Results conform to previous studies in that on the average




roughly ten percent variations in air pollution dosages yield




approximately $450 variations of the opposite sign for residential




property values.  A comparison of regressions employing the




disaggregated FHA data with regressions using Chicago census tract




data gave no support to the hypothesis of the presence of aggregation




bias in the latter regressions.  Nor was there any conclusive




evidence that the discrepancies between years of property sale





-------
                                iii






studies introduced any serious statistical bias.  Local tax




assessments were found to be poor proxies for act;ual market sales




prices, though FHA assessments were good proxies.




     The hypothesis that residential property values decline at a




decreasing rate with respect to increasing air pollution dosages




was subjected to several different tests.  No grounds were discovered




justifying the hypothesis' rejection.  The hypothesis that land




values are more sensitive to air pollution dosages than are the




values of landed improvements was also supported by the results.




Finally, the skewness of the annual distribution of monthly air




pollution dosages was found to contribute to property values,




though no support was found for the contribution of the distribution's





-------
                                iv






                         GENERAL SUMMARY




Introduction




     There have been many diverse attempts to provide some




quantitative indication of the willingness of urban air pollution




sufferers to pay for reductions in air pollution dosages.  Scattered




not very liberally among all the interview surveys, the speculations




about health related costs, the outright guesses, and the questionable




extrapolations from materials damages studies are studies which




venture to establish quantitatively the extent of covariation




between residential real estate values and air pollutant dosages.




The results of all those studies with which the writer is familiar




are synthesized in Appendix B.  With one single exception, a




summary of which is presented in Appendix A, these studies have




universally found an inverse relation between property values and




air pollution which, for residential properties, amounts to an




average marginal capitalized loss of between $100 and $1,000 per




residential unit.  An attempt is made in Appendix B to comprehend




why the results of Appendix A do not complement the findings of




other studies.




     Employing the same fundamental economic-theoretic rationale as




have all previous studies except that in Appendix A, the purposes of




the present investigation are tyro:   (1)  to test empirically





-------
than have been previously tested; and (2)  to test the previously




tested and the new hypotheses with data certainly more complete




and probably more accurate than in previous studies.  A general




idea of the extent to which the main body of this investigation




fulfills these two purposes is presented in this summary.






The Data




     a)  The data consists of structural, site, purchaser, sale,




and neighborhood characteristics of each of 1,288 FHA-insured single




family residential properties in the City of Chicago, Illinois, from




January, 1964, through December, 1967.  Excluding transformations,




297 separate bits of information were collected and collated for




each of the 1,288 transactions.




     b)  Dosages of suspended particulates and sulfur dioxide were




calculated for the location of each transaction from monthly




arithmetic means of samples collected by the Chicago Air Pollution




Control District.






Hypotheses Derived from Economic Considerations




     a)  To the extent that air pollution effects are relevant




considerations to the 'selector of a residential property, the value




of the effects of pollution is embodied in a single entity,




residential property values, and cet. par., differences in the





-------
                                vi






 In  short,  air  pollution effects are capitalized into property




 value:;, and, if disutility is on the average derived from air




 pollution  effects, an inverse relation will exist between air




 pollution  dosages and these values.




     b)  Hints have appeared in earlier studies that the aggregate




 air pollution  damage function may be increasing at a decreasing




 rate over  a fairly wide range of dosages.  An attempt is made here




 to provide a rationale for a declining marginal air pollution




 damage function.




     c)  All previous studies of the covariation between air




 pollution  and  urban property values have been devoted to the




 entire property, land and improvements.  Thus no attempt has been




 made to distinguish between the effects of air pollution upon land




 and upon landed improvements.  A hypothesis is derived in this




 study to the effect that the marginal damage function for land will




 decline at a rate more rapid than the marginal damage function for




 landed improvements; and that land values will be more responsive




 to air pollution dosages than will the values of landed improvements.




     d)  When  future air pollution dosages are uncertain, the




 features of the air pollution frequency distribution relevant to



 the receptor may not be adequately described by the distribution's



mathematical expectation.  In particular, the market may evaluate




 the variance and the skewness of the distribution.





-------
                                vii






dosages  can  imply a preference ordering over possible future states




based upon a decision criterion in which the sufferer's objective




is  to make his maximum possible losses as small as possible.




     f)  For given supply conditions, the market price of a




residential property is determined by the market's expectations




about the future values of it structural, site, purchaser, sale,




and neighborhood characteristics.  These expectations can be formed




in many ways.  In the case of air pollution, it seems likely these




expectations are formed almost entirely on the basis of a history of




past air pollution dosages.  One can therefore inquire into the




influence the various parts of this history have upon property




values.






Hypotheses Derived from Statistical Considerations




     g)   All previous studies of this sort have employed property




characteristics and property value data in which the air pollution



data postdated the property data by anywhere from four to seven




years.  This discrepancy can cause the air pollution coefficients



to be understated.  The data available to this study permit one to




test for this source of bias by matching property value data for




any one of four years.



     h)   It can be shown that unless all households in a group




suffer the same marginal damages from air pollution and unless the





-------
                                  viii



  described by a stable linear model, then air pollution coefficients


  calculated from such aggregated data can be biased.  By comparing

  results obtained with completely disaggregated data with results

  obtained using grouped data from the U. S. Census, one can ascertain
\l
  whether the results with the census data exhibit aggregation bias.

        i)  Records on FHA assessed  property values are perhaps more


  readily available than are records on actual market sales prices.

  The data permit the comparison of estimated air pollution damages


  when  FHA assessments are used as property values and when actual


  market sales prices are used.'

        j)  Local assessments of property values are widely collected

  and are readily accessible throughout the country.   The data used

  here  permit the comparison of estimated air pollution damages when

  FHA assessments are used as property values and when actual market


  sales prices are used.

        k)  It is to be expected that air pollution dosages and


  property maintenance outlays will be positively related.  The

•  presence in the FHA data of a measure of maintenance costs allows a

  test  of this possible relation.



  The Results

        a)  Results support the hypothesis of an inverse relation

  between air pollution dosages and residential property values.


-------
                                Ix






average the sum of the damage elasticities for sulfur dioxide and




suspended particulates in the City of Chicago is between -.30 and




-.40.  Average marginal capitalized damages appear to be about




$450 for an additional ten micrograms per cubic meter per twenty-four




hours of suspended particulates plus an additional part per billion




by volume per twenty-four hours of sulfur dioxide.  These results




have been .obtained employing the completely disaggregated FHA data.




No solid evidence of serious multicollinearity of the pollution




variables with other explanatory variables was discovered.




     b)  Eleven different partitions of the disaggregated FHA




data were carried out so as to run separate regressions on samples




whose annual arithmetic mean pollution dosages differed.  In no




case were there any grounds for rejection of the hypothesis that




willingness to pay to avoid air pollution dosages increases at a




decreasing rate.




     c)  As hypothesized, land values appear to be more sensitive




to air pollution dosages than do landed improvements.  Average




marginal capitalized reductions in land values were about half the




average marginal capitalized damages to property values, though,




on the average, land values constituted substantially less than




one-quarter of property values.  Similarly, the sum of the damage




elasticities in the property value regressions is always less than





-------
     d)  At no time did the inclusion of the second moment of a




calendar year's air pollution distribution yield a statistically




significant result, though the signs of the coefficients for the




variable representing variance were consistently negative.  Results




for the third moment were only slightly ambiguous.  In two cases




significant results with a negative sign were obtained when the




mean of the skewness variables was positive.  In that third case




where statistically insignificant results were obtained, the mean of




the skewness variable wae nearly zero.




     e)  A meaningful test of the minimax decision criterion was




inhibited by serious multicollinearity between minimum, maximum,




and mean suspended particulate dosages as well between maximum and




mean sulfur dioxide dosages.




     f)  Because of a relative lack of success in constructing a




computer program capable of estimation when two or more variables




in a cross-sectional regression are distributed lags, no meaningful




estimates were obtained of the contribution the various parts of




an air pollution history make to current air pollution damages.




     g)  Using the same set of FHA transactions from one regression




to another and permitting the regressions to differ only in the




years in which air pollution dosages occurred, it was difficult




on intuitive grounds to discern any important differences in the





-------
                                xi






statistical bias in the air pollution damage estimates due to




discrepancies in the year of property sale observations and the




year of air pollution dosage observations is not immediately




obvious from inspection of the air pollution coefficients.  However,




this intuitive identity of the coefficients can not be supported




on statistical grounds.




     h)  An intuitive comparison of the air pollution coefficients




obtained using census tract data and those obtained using the




disaggregated FHA data failed to reveal any significant "common sense"




differences.  However, the hypothesis of the statistical identity




of the two sets of coefficients could not be accepted.  When the




level of aggregation was increased to include in each observation




"averages" known as community areas constructed from several




census tracts, there was neither any common sense nor any statistical




identity of the two sets of coefficients.




     i)  A comparison of the air pollution coefficients obtained




when actual market sale price is employed as the regressand with




the coefficients obtained using FHA assessed value as the regressand




reveals an intuitive identity of the coefficients and at least a




partial statistical identity.




     j)  A comparison similar to that in i) above for actual market




sales prices and local assessed values reveals no intuitive and





-------
                                xii






Was discovered, the difficulty of locally obtaining data on




individual householder attributes would seem to preclude the




use of data obtained from local,assessments.  The importance of




this bias is evidence in the fairly substantial changes which occur




in the standard errors of the air pollution coefficients whenever




some measure of householder income is not included as a regr.essor.




     k)  The air pollution coefficients obtained when maintenance




expenses were included as a regressand had negative signs.  It is




therefore concluded that the maintenance measure employed was an




inadequate measure of actual maintenance expenses.  To assert




otherwise is to conclude that air pollution dosages have no




effect upon maintenance expenses.  This latter assertion is




incompatible with the other results of this study.






Research Extensions




     The study concludes with suggestions about possible extensions





-------
                                xiil






                        TABLE OF CONTENTS




Section                                                     Page




Acknowledgement                                              i




Author's Abstract                                           ii




General Summary                                             iv




Table of Contents                                         xiii




List of Tables                                              xv




List of Figures                                           xvii




INTRODUCTION                                                 1




THE THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK                                    4




     Basis of the Offer Function                             5




     The Marginal Air Pollution Damage Function              11




     Relative Damages to Land and Improvements               18




     Air Pollution Damages Due to Uncertainty                21




     Householder Decision Criteria under Uncertainty         26




     The Formation of Air Pollution Dosage Expectations       31




THE EMPIRICAL BACKGROUND                                     38




     General Nature of the Data                              38




     The Air Pollution Data                                  41




     Simultaneity of Air Pollution and Transactions  Data      46




     Aggregation Bias                                        47




     Use of Actual Market Sales Prices                       51




     Possibilities in^the Use of Assessed Property Values     52





-------
                                xiv

THE VARIABLES                                                54

     Dependent Variables    .                                 54

     Explanatory Variables                                   56

THE RESULTS                ,                                  71

     Statistical Attributes of the Data                      72

     The Inverse Relation Between Air Pollution Dosages      76

         and Property Value

     Effect of Discrepancies Between Dates of Air Pollution  83

         and Property Data

     The Use of Assessed Property Values                     88

     Maintenance Expenditures                                91

     Effects of Dosages Upon Site Values                     91

     Declining Marginal Damages                              93

     The Minimax Decision Criterion                          97

     The Cubic Utility Function                              97

     Adaptive Expectations                                  101

SOME DESIRABLE RESEARCH EXTENSIONS                          103
     Theoretical Issues                                     lOh

     Estimation                                             112

     Empirical Issues                                       118

     Summary and Conclusions                                121

FOOTNOTES                                                   12U

BIBLIOGRAPHY                                                131

APPENDICES

     Appendix A.  "Property Values and the Demand for Clean  A-l
         Air", by Kenneth F. Wieand.
     Appendix B.  "A Comment on Wieand", by R. J. Anderson,  B-l

-------
                                 XV
                          LIST OF  TABLES
 Table                                                         Page

 1.  Annual Arithmetic Mean Pollution Dosage by  Station          43
      and Year.

 2.  Stations Having Differences in Annual  Air Pollution         45
      Distributions.

 3.  Arithmetic Means and Standard  Deviations of Original        73
      Values of Nonpollution Variables.

 4.  Arithmetic Means and Standard  Deviations of Original        74
      Values of Representative Pollution Variables.

 5.  Simple Correlation Coefficients for 1967 Observations       75

 6.  Initial Regressions.  Dependent Variable, In(COSTS).        77

 7.  Initial Regressions with One Pollution Variable.            78

 8.  initial Regressions without In(DISSM)  and In(DLAKE).        80

 9.  Regressions for DISSM and DLAKE Partitions.                81

10.  Simple Correlation Coefficients for DISSM and DLAKE         81
      Partitions.

11.  Regressions for INDUT, BLK66,  and INC66 Partitions.         83

12.  Regressions Exhibiting Discrepancies in Air Pollution  and   84
      .Property Sale Data.

13.  Analysis of Covariance of 1967 Disaggregated FHA  Data.     85

14.  Regression Results for Census  Data. Dependent  Variable,    87
      ln(MVAL6).

15.  Analysis of Covariance of Disaggregated FHA and Census     87
      Data.

16.  Regressions with In(FHAVL), In(TAXES), and  In(MAINT) as     90

-------
                                xvi
17.  Regressions for Site Values.  Dependent variable,          92
      .Ln(PSITE).

18.  Regressions with ln(SUL65)  Partitioned.  Dependent         94
      variable, In(COSTS).

19.  Comparison of Logarithmic Means and Pollution              95
      Coefficients.

20.  Regressions for Minimum and Maximum Pollution Dosages.      98

21.  Regressions on Second and Third Moments of Pollution       99
      Dosages.


-------
                                xvii
                         LIST OF FIGURES
Figure                                                        Page
1.  Possible Householder Losses from Errors in Forecasting     29
      Air Pollution Dosages.

2.  Comparison of Kinimax z, z , and Expected Utility z, "z,    32
      under Uncertainty about Air Pollution Dosages.

3.  Locations of Air Pollution Monitoring Stations and         40

-------
                                •i-
Introduction




     In the past five or ten years, the attention which air




pollution problems have received has generated a wide variety of




proposals for their alleviation.  Present in all these proposals




has been some notion of a damage function relating air pollution




dosages to the market value of the foregone production and



consumption opportunities suffered by receptors.  Most academic




discussions of these proposals have proceeded in a world of




certainty, a world in which the values of all variables relevant




to the decision process can always be consistently and




costlessly predicted with zero probability of error.  Most of




the time property rights in the air resource are assumed to be




assigned to a control agency whose tremendous clairvoyance




and omniscience enables if. to select effortlessly or cause to



occur that level of pollutant emissions synonymous with ambient




air concentrations minimizing the sum of sufferer damage and




emitter control costs.  Under these conditions, discussions of




optimal control instruments become trivial exercises in which




the only matters of interest are value-loaded statements about




whose judgments are to count.  Questions of real economic



interest would occur only when it is supposed that the control



agency knows of no systematic way to put its perfect information




-------
                                -2-






     However, once it Is recognized that the discovery of that




pollution program minimizing the sum of emitter and receptor




costs is itself costly, important differences among alternative




control instruments become apparent.  Ultimately, the criterion




for selection of a control instrument must be the minimization




of the sum of emitter and receptor costs and all parties',




including regulatory bodies', informational, contractual and




policing (ICP) costs.  Even assuming all property rights to the




air resource are always initially vested in a control agency,




the ICP costs of alternative control instruments can differ




widely.  For example, the use of the effluent charge as the sole




instrument of control requires an intimate knowledge of the




behavior of the air pollution damage function.  But when the




effluent charge is employed along with an already established




ambient air standard, knowledge of neither the receptor damage




function nor the emitter control cost function is required.  All




the agency need do is vary the charge in a manner causing the




ambient air standard not to be exceeded.  Of course, though ICP




costs are relatively low in this latter case, the ambient air




standard may be identified with substantial permanent or periodic




deviations from minimization of the sum of receptor and emitter




costs.  The probable costs of this deviation must be weighed





-------
                                -3-






minlmizing effluent charges as well as against the costs of




employing a suboptimal effluent charge as the sole control




instrument.




     The formal consideration of the preceding statements




immediately leads one into the formidable quicksands of



problems in decision-making under uncertainty.  In this paper



the intent is not to enter these sands but instead to provide an




input which in the context of air pollution concerns can assist




in this decision-making.  The particular purpose is to




investigate the urban air pollution damage function as it is




registered in differential market prices of residential property.




This will by no means be the first time this function has been




studied in this manner, e.g., Anderson and Crocker [l]; Ridker




and Henning [2]; Ridker {3, pp. 141-151] ; Zerbe [4]; Wieand[5];




and Peckham [6].  By using sopewhat more complex specifications



and a set of data appearing to have greater informational




content, this study's purpose is to ascertain the sensitivity



of damage functions derived by means of differential land values




to differences in specifications and differences in data.  If




results do not appear overly sensitive to data and specification




differences, then simpler and less costly specifications and




daca sets can be used to obtain the damage function with little




-------
                                 -4-






 control instrument more likely to approach a continuing




, minimization of the sum of emitter control costs and receptor




 damage costs can then be employed.  Less obtusely stated,  the




 question being asked here is whether any additional worthwhile




 information about urban air pollution damage functions can be




 obtained by working with property value models having somewhat




 more complex specifications and more complete data than in




 previous studies.






 The Theoretical Framework




      Lind [8], building upon the work of Strotz [ ?], has shown,




 given certain simplifying assumptions, that the difference in




 the market price of two sites represents the difference in the




 aggregate willingness to pay for the sites net of any difference



 in profits or consumer surplus.  Thus if two sites are similar




 in all respects except air quality, the difference in their




 values represents the markets'  willingness to pay for reductions




 in air pollution dosages.   When all consumers do not regard  two




 sites as perfect substitutes in all respects except air quality,




 then some air pollution damages will be capitalized into durable




 and immobile improvements and losses in consumer surplus.




 However, if the characteristics of these sites and other assets



 enter individual utility functions in an additive manner,  then





-------
                                -5-






bound on air pollution damages.  Furthermore, when sites are not




viewed as perfect substitutes by consumers, a substantial portion




of damages will still be registered in differential property




values, where a property includes the site and the immobile and




durable improvements thereon.




     For each time period dealt with in this study a long-run




equilibrium is presumed to exist in all housing characteristics.




Thus no supplier of housing characteristics is presumed to be




able to increase his net revenues by adjusting the stock or the




location of housing characteristics.  Similarly,  no individual




buyer of housing 'characteristics can increase his utility by




purchasing a different package of characteristics or by changing




';he location of his residence. ; In short, given the market




structure, all locations are presumed to be held  by those




participating in activities yielding the highest  property values.




Our task is to explain the differences in these values.  Assuming




that all suppliers of housing characteristics face the same




capitalization rates and cost structures in the locale of interest,




these value differences are accounted for by consumer evaluations




of differing locational characteristics.






     Basis of the Offer Function.  The point of departure





-------
                                -6-
consume.r behavior.  The consumer is represented as the



embodiment of a well-behaved utility function, U [z(x)], where



z  is an mxl vector of quantities of characteristics and x is an



nxl vector of the quantities of the goods in which the


                          2
characteristics are found.   Thus housing is a bundle of



characteristics households produce with their own time and skills



using purchased inputs which include buildings and space.  In



short, the consumer ranks characteristics, and because he ranks



characteristics, he indirectly ranks goods, which in this essay



will be housing locations.  The consumer's problem is therefore



to maximize U subject to the conditions



     c'x = y



       z = Bx



       Zj  x >_ 0



where c .is the nxl vector of prices associated with the goods,



B is an raxn matrix, and y is income.  It is proved in Anderson



and Crocker [l]  and restated in Appendix B of the present essay,



that the utility maximizing quantities of the various



characteristics are functions of the prices of the various goods



in which they reside and consumer incomes.  That is, one is



justified in writing c = c(z ) y)  where c (.) is the consumer's



offer function.




-------
                                -7-






consumer evaluate all goods in which a characteristic entering




his utility function is found.  Since a house may embody




characteristics found in a wide variety of other goods, a




complete empirical specification of this offer function would




require the simultaneous specification of offer functions for




all those goods also embodying some of the characteristics




embodied in housing.  For example, if the individual at some set




of relative prices for the goods in which they are found is




willing to substitute clean air for enclosed three dimensional




space, there is no ji priori reason why his search for clean air




must be limited to housing locations.  It would therefore appear




that a study of housing demand would also require a simultaneous




study of the demand for mountain recreation.




     Actually, as Lancaster [14] emphasizes, the characteristics




embodied in some goods, for given relative prices of goods, will




represent inefficient consumer choices and can therefore be




disregarded.  But in any empirical application the elements of




the B matrix must be specified, an ambiguous task for which there




is little if any theoretical guide.  Neither the researcher nor




the consumer are likely to possess the skills and willingness to




survey and count completely and simultaneously all characteristics




to be found in housing.  If one introduces, as we shall, dated





-------
                                -8-






required for the researcher to perceive all gradients of the




consumption technology are indeed astounding.  The same point




can be made for. the consumer.  Though it is true a great many




things can be measured if the urge for measurement is strong




enough, the very fact that some urging is required implies a




cost.  One can therefore reasonably presume the consumer strives




to satisfy a craving for simplicity by means of some aggregation




procedure which reduces at some stage the rank of the B matrix he




must confront.




     Consider the following scheme which in certain of its




fundamentals is similar to that presented by Green [15, pp. 9-32],




In order to conserve his means of surveying and counting, the




consumer completely disregards some commodities and aggregates




over others having collections'of characteristics intended to




serve a more or less broad function, e.j;., housing, food,




entertainment.  In the first decision stage, the allocation of




the consumer's budget on the basis of price indices of the




commodities forming such broad groupings does not make an




intolerable difference in the decision problem with which the




consumer is confronted.  We assume his demand for the broad




grouping "housing" or any other broad grouping to be altogether




independent of air pollution considerations.  Only after this





-------
                                -9-


housing characteristics evaluated.  One of these evaluated

characteristics is the presence of air pollution.

     It is well known that if the utility function U tz(x)] is

strongly separable in the sense of Goldman and Uzawa [16], the

quantity of each commodity purchased with the consumer operating

under ft. two-stage procedure will be identical to the quantity

purchased if the consumer's purchases had all been made in' one

stage.  That is, if we assume the commodities embodying

characteristics entering the utility function are divided into

three groups of commodities, H, I, and J, where H is housing,

then strong separability is defined as:

                          heH
              = 0  for
   D  xh                  ici
                       Rnln J - ft

where i; j , and h are commodities having at least one

characteristic not in common.  Given this restriction upon the

utility function, if the consumer allocates his budget in the

first stage so as to maximize a utility function having groups

of characteristics embodied in groups of goods as its arguments,

then the consumer can maximize his overall utility by maximizing

a utility function in the second stage having characteristics


-------
                                -10-


a utility maximizing allocation of the consumer's budget among

housing locations is therefore not inconsistent with a utility

maximizing allocation of this budget among all goods.  This

result dotes not necessarily imply that groups of characteristics

interdependent in demand do not exist.  It only implies that the
         »
individual property buyer groups all interdependent

characteristics so that he makes his final house purchase decision

in terms of the mutually independent groupings which we are

presumed to be able to describe.  Conceptually, these

separability notions imply that air pollution damages to housing

will be relatively greater because they permit the consumer to

respond to changes in air pollution dosages only by a

redistribution of his expenditures among characteristics in the

housing group rather than among all groups.  However, in terms

of estimating the effects of air pollution upon the demand for

housing, the failure of these separability notions to be

fulfilled means that the characteristics of certain goods which

contribute to the explanation of variations in offer prices for

housing are not being included.  If these characteristics are not

orthogonal to air pollution dosages and if they contribute

positively to offer prices, then air pollution damages will tend

to be biased downward.  Similarly, if they contribute negatively,


-------
                                -11-




     On the basis of the above statements, the offer function to


be estimated is a quantity weighted average of implicit prices


for combinations of characteristics embodied in a commodity or


bundle making up something called a housing location.  It should


be emphasized that each price observation is presumed to be


attached to one unit of a unique commodity, a housing location


which is objectively distinguishable by its combination of


characteristics.  The c^ are therefore observations on the


market prices of distinct goods.  They represent T observable


prices of T different goods.  Each refers to one and only one


house.   Therefore, making the not unreasonable assumption that


each residential property owner owns only one house and that


each residential property is owned by only one owner, the offer


price for housing and consumer expenditures for housing are

          4
identical.




     The Marginal Air Pollution  Damage Function.  This essay's


prime concern is the connection between air pollution and land


and property prices, and between land and property prices and air

                  5
pollution damages.   The notion that air pollution damages are in


fact registered in differential property values is quite comforting


to anyone who has ever experienced the theoretical and empirical


difficulties associated with the   employment  of  alternative



-------
                                -12-






pollution damages.  Nevertheless, the ability of an approach to




provide insight into one question makes one wonder whether it




might also provide insight into related questions.  In




particular, can anything be said about the form of the relation




between air pollution dosages and property values?  Furthermore,




given that some insight can be acquired into the form of this




relation, are there any inferences which can be drawn about the




form of the relation between air pollution dosages and air




pollution damages apart from any capitalization of the latter




into property values?  In an earlier effort of the writer and




R. .1. Anderson, Jr. til, empirical results over some interval




of increasing air pollution dosages pointed to the possibility




of a declining marginal property damage function as well as a




declining property damage elasticity.  No explanation of the




phenomenon was offered however.




     In accordance with the Lancaster formulation, the




household is viewed in the following as a firm selling a bundle




of housing characteristics to itself for a price equal to its




maximum willingness to pay for that bundle.  For simplicity, all




households are treated as identical.  The bundle of housing




characteristics and the goods used to obtain these characteristics




are each assumed to fulfill the conditions for a composite good.





-------
                                -13-

that x and y can each be defined by a scalar rather than a vector.
     Given the above conditions, the householder's problem is to
maximize
(1)          U = cz - c^x
subject to
             z = z(x) ,
where U is the householder's utility, z is the bundle of housing
characteristics, and x is the collection of housing location goods.
The unit cost of the collection of goods is c_, and the unit cost of
                                             X,
the bundle of characteristics is c.  U can thus be regarded as a measure
of the Marshallian consumer surplus.  The first order condition
for a maximum is
(2)         ajL- c£5.-  cx=o.
Air pollution dosages are specific to location.  For locational
equilibrium to prevail, it is necessary and sufficient that each
household occupy the most expensive available property it is
willing to buy and that each available property be occupied by
that household willing to pay the highest price.  The change in
the bundle of characteristics resulting from any change in the
household's location is given by

-------
                                -14-





The condition of (2) implies



(4)          cx = c i£





and the change in consumer surplus accompanying such a change in



location is



(5)          dU « (zdc - xdCx) + (cdz - cxdx)



The first-order condition of (4) is always fulfilled.  Therefore,



upon substituting (3) and (4) into (5), we have



(6)          dU - (zdc - xdcv) + (c |5. dx - c |5. dx)
                            *       oX        oX


                = dc  - xdc
                    x      x


     If there is to be locational equilibrium, dU = 0.  Thus (6)



becomes

                               i

(7)          dc  = dc  z  .

               x       x


By hypothesis, c = c(p) and ££   0, where p refers to air



pollution dosages.  Therefore, from (7)



(8)          dcx   _ dc  z   < 0

              dc     dp  x      '


since a positive quantity of housing characteristics can be



obtained only from a positive quantity of housing location goods.



The difference between dc /dp and dc/dp is obviously dependent



upon the ratio of z to x.  In general, it is to be expected that



0 < z/x 1. 1, since the number of housing locations the consumer



at least initially chooses among seems likely to exceed the




-------
                                -15-
to be relevant.  One can therefore conclude that the marginal


air pollution damages to goods from which housing characteristics


can be obtained can exceed the marginal damages to bundles of


housing characteristics.
(9) ,






and


(9a)
     Furthermore,
             dp
             d2c
                      z  d2c
                      x  dp
dc
                      dp
                                 dc  d(z/x)
           dp    dp
                               dc  d(z/x)
                                            x
                               dp    dp



As previously noted, z/x is positive and dc/dp is negative.  One



of the major economic features of air pollution is that it



reduces the output (characteristics) to be obtained from any



given mix and magnitude of inputs (goods).  Thus d(z/x)/dp



is also negative.  It is therefore immediately obvious that if

       • 7    9     ?     2
either d c/dp  or d cx/dp  is positive, the sign of one cannot



be inferred from the sign of the other.  However, if either can



be shown to be negative, then it follows that the other must also


be negative.  That is, if air pollution damages to housing



characteristics increase at a decreasing rate, then air pollution



damages to goods capable of generating housing characteristics




-------
                                -16-
                                                         o

     In location theory, it is widely acknowledged that d c is




negative with respect to any variable which dxffers in magnitude




from one location to another and to whose increased presence




disutility is attached.  The reasoning goes as follows.




Locational equilibrium requires that households be unable to




increase (U = cz - ex) by any move.  Given that air pollution
                    X



and property values are inversely related, the household can




increase the quantity it can purchase of the goods embodying




any bundle of housing characteristics for a particular money




outlay by moving to an area subject to greater pollution dosages.




However, the household's willingness to pay, for a given bundle of




housing characteristics at the higher pollution location has




declined.  This implies that in equilibrium




(10)         dcx     dc



             dp      dp




In short, in locational equilibrium a change due to pollution in




the price of goods embodying a given bundle of housing




characteristics is exactly offset by the change in the





-------
                                -17-
 if  this  equilibrium  is  to be maintained, it is necessary that

 with  increased air pollution, householder willingness to pay

 decline  at a rate less  rapid than the decline in the market

 prices of goods embodying housing characteristics.  If differences

 in willingness to pay are interpreted as the air pollution

 damages  the householder perceives to be imposed upon a given

 bundle of housing characteristics, this implies that the

 marginal air pollution damage function is declining with

 increased dosages and is declining at a rate less rapid than the

 decline  in the price of housing goods.  Otherwise the location of

 each householder would be indeterminant or each householder

 could alwayn increase U(z) by moving to locations having the

 highest pollution dosages.  This is because the incremental

 householder benefits implicit in the rate of decline of the

 price of housing goods would ultimately exceed the additional
                                 /<
 householder damages implicit in the rate of the reduction in

 householder willingness to pay.

     If households are now permitted to differ in their

 sensitivity to air pollution dosages, the above implies that

 those households for whom dc/dp is relatively high will tend to

 locate where air pollution dosages are relatively low; and those
                              ,  !»
 households for whom dc/dp is relatively low, will tend to locate
                                I


-------
                                -18-

of  (10) states that when dc/dp is high, dcv/dp must also be high.
                                          X
Pollution sensitive people bid the most for low pollution locations
because these people attach greater disutility to a little bit
of  pollution than does anyone else.  Sites are thus assigned on
the basis of the individual's pollution sensitivity, with the
most pollution sensitive being assigned to the low pollution
sites and least pollution sensitive being assigned to the high
pollution sites.  The absolute magnitude of dc/dp thus declines
over an array of locations ordered on the basis of the magnitude
of  the air pollution dosages to which they are subject.  One
would therefore expect to find when comparing marginal property
damage Junctions for high pollution locations to those for low
pollution locations that the absolute magnitude of the latter is
less than the former.  If the "production function" z(x)  is
homogeneous of degree one so that changes in x lead to identical
percentage changes in z, then this conclusion also holds for the
elasticity of the value of a bundle of housing characteristics
with respect to air pollution dosages.

  >  Relative Damages to Land and Improvements.  Additional
interesting results can be obtained by retaining the same assumptions
but revising the simple formulation beginning with (1) so that land
and nonland goods embodying housing characteristics are

-------
                                -19-
permanent features of a location.  For practical purposes, they

can include such features as utilities and man-made changes  in

topography as well as the unimproved space associated with the

site.  Jsing the land-non]and distinction, (1) becomes

(11)         U = czC^, y - ^ XL - CN XN,

where U, c, and z are defined as before.  Land and nonland goods

are represented respectively by :e and x , while CL and c

represent their prices.  The first-order conditions for a

maximum are

(12)        JMJ  =  c 3z_  _  CL  =0
            3xL      9xL

             9U  _  c 3_z  _  Cjj  = 0.
            3xN      8xN

Performing the same set of operations as in  (3) -  (7), one obtains

(13)         z dc - ^ dcL - Xjj dcN = 0

and

(14)         dcL    zdc    XN
             __  __     ^


Thus, in value terms, given that z ^_ x^ + x^ and dc > 1, it

follows that (30) will be greater than unity.  That is, marginal

air pollution damages to a bundle of housing characteristics will

be registered to a greater extent in land than in  the nonland

goods which contribute to housing characteristics.  In general,


-------
                                -20-




value of the characteristics it produces, the greater will be



the do,  caused by a change in air pollution dosages.  Again, if



the "production function" Z(XL, Xjj) is homogeneous of degree one



so that equLproportional increases in XL and XN lead to identical



percentage increases in z, then marginal rates of substitution



between land and nonland good remain unchanged and a conclusion



similar to (14) holds for the elasticity of land values and



nonland values with respect to variations in air pollution



dosages.  If the elasticity of substitution between land and



nonland goods is positive and if the supply elasticity of land



goods is less than the supply elasticity of nonland goods, the



conclusion of (30) is strengthened, for the magnitude of dc
                                                           Li

relative to variations in dc will be accentuated.  However, as


land goods are substituted for nonland goods because of the



change in relative prices, nonland goods will exhibit the



greatest relative decline in .quantity employed as a consequence



of an increase in air pollution dosages.   In other words, given



the correctness of the preceding assumptions, for a given


population air pollution increases what is typically known as



"urban sprawl," the spreading out over the landscape of streets,


huge signs, and one story buildings.


     A number of reasonable offhand estimates about the likely




-------
                                -21-






First, land goods probably contribute less than one-third of the




value of a typical bundle of housing characteristics, if that




much.  Second, the elasticity of substitution of land for




nonland goods in housing is generally acknowledged to be slightly




less than unity, e.g., Muth [27, p. 82 ].  Finally, it is




intuitively obvious that the supply elasticity of residential




land in an urban area must be substantially less than the supply




elasticity for nonland residential goods.  There are thus strong




2. priori empirical as well as theoretical grounds for expecting




land values to be more responsive than nonland values to variations




in air pollution dosages whenever any statistical tests are made.




Contrary test results would more likely justify dismissal of the




test on grounds of specification or measurement error rather than a




failure to accept the hypothesis.






     Air Pollution Damages Due to Uncertainty.  To this point, the




discussion has implicitly assumed that for those variables whose




future values are not largely subject to the householder's control, only




the expected value of the variable's frequency distribution is relevant




to the householder's decisions.  In other words, certainty equivalence




has been assumed such that the first moment of the air pollution




frequency distribution at a particular site adequately summarizes the entire





-------
                                -22-



dosages has been treated as identical in situations where perfect


foresight is lacking and in situations where it is present.  The


householder's behavior at a point in time is therefore viewed as


invariant with respect to the probability of error in his forecast


of expected air pollution dosages.


     In the following, we continue to express the multivalued
                          t

expected results associated with alternative time-states as


probability distributions rather than assuming that the

                                                    O
householder sets these states out in extensive form.   That is, we


add to the set of air pollution characteristics relevant to the


property buyer various derivative statistical measures of air


pollution frequency distributions.  In particular, by assuming;


U(z) to be cubic in air pollution dosages, we show the relevance


of the first three moments of the air pollution frequency

                                      9
distribution to air pollution damages.   However, this demonstration


does not assert that only the first three moments count, for, as


Richter [22] has shown, an nth degree polynomial for U(z) implies


and is implied by the assumption that only the first n moments are


to count.  In short, by assuming a utility function of the proper


degree one can justify the use of any number of moments (until


their values tend to zero).


     Assuming a one to one correspondence between the implicit



-------
                             -23-




householder"s utility, U, we can rewrite c = c  (p) as


(15)         U = U(p) , and  3.U     < 0 uniformly,


given that fewer air pollution dosages are preferred to more.


Expanding (15) in a Taylor series  about a mean value, p,  ignoring


moments above the third, and taking the expected value yields


(16)         E [ U(p*)]  =  U(p) +
                                      !  _2/   \e  j  _3;
                                       VaP /          V3P /
As a random variable, p = p*, and


             a2 = E(p* - p)2


             a3 - E(P* -p)3


     As noted above, taking the utility of dirtier air  to be a


function of the first three moments of p*'s distribution about


its mean is equivalent to assuming U(p*)  to be a cubic  of the


form


(17)         U(p*) = p* + bp*2  4-  gp*3


Upon .taking the expected value of (17) we obtain

                                          2             3
(18)         E  U(p*)   =  E(p*)  + bE(p*)   +  g E(p*)


where


(19)         E(p*)2  = o2  +  [E(p*)] 2


and


(20)         E(p*)3  =a   - 2 [E(p*)] 3  +  3E(p*)2 E(p*).


Substitution of (19) and (20) into (18) gives


(21)         E [U(p*)l -  E(p*) + b [E(p*)J 2 + g [E(p*>] 3 +

-------
                                -24-




Taking the partial derivative of  (21) with respect  to  E(p*), we



get



(22)       9 E  [l)(p*) 3  =  1 + 2bE(p*) + 3g  fE(p*) I2   +3g  a2

               3 E(p*)                                             „           .

                        -  1 + 2bE(p*) + 3g  [E(p*)T   +  3g(E(p*r  -  [E(p*)]ZJ-
                        -  1 + 2bE(p*) + 3g E(p*)?



This is a quadratic having roots



             -2b 1  [2b2 - 4(3g) ]2

                      6g



Thus if the marginal utility of dirtier air is always  to be



negative, then



             2b2  < 4(3g).



That is, for (22) to be negative, it is required  that



(23)         b2  < 3g

       o
Since b  is always positive, g must also be positive if  (23)  is



to hold true.  Given that g must be positive, the sign for


  2    —2
 3 U/3 p   comes from (16) and  (21) where



(24)         9E [U(p*)l   .  32U/9 p2  = 3gE(p*)  + b

               803              2



                          =  3g"p + b


            —                  2    —2
Clearly, if p  £ -b/3g, then  3 U/3 p   10, which is  consistent



with the statements about the sign of the marginal air pollution



damage function in (9a).  The assumption of p  1  -b/3g amounts




-------
                                -25-




                       3    —3
The correct sign for  3 U/8 p  can also be obtained from (16) and



 (21) since



 (25)         9E [U(p*) ]  _  ( 93U/9 p3)    = g.

                      -
The requirement from (23) that g be positive therefore assures



that  33U/9 p3  <  0.



     Our conclusion from (24) and (25) above is that the



householder attaches disutility to increasing uncertainty, as



measured by variance, of air pollution dosages.  Furthermore,



given equivalent expected values and variances, he prefers those



air pollution frequency distributions skewed toward the lower



range of dosages.  Treating these derivative statistical



measures as distinct characteristics, we therefore view each



residential property as giving rise to at least three air



pollution characteristics, the mean, the variance, and the



skewness of the property's air pollution frequency distribution.



     As we earlier noted, there is no particularly defensible



reason other than investigative convenience to assert that only



the first moment, or, for that matter, the first three moments



of the distribution of air pollution dosages enter as arguments



into the housing consumer's utility function.  In effect, the



problem of discovering what these arguments are with respect to




-------
                                -26-




Investigator can therefore hope to do is to specify models


capable of being empirically evaluated.




     Householder Decision Criteria Under Uncertainty.  There


exist several alternative decision criteria conceivably


applicable to a householder faced with uncertainty about the future


pollution dosages to which he will be subject.  Each of these


alternatives implies a preference ordering over possible future


states based upon a criterion other than the maximization of

                 10
expected utility.    Many of these criteria cannot be meaningfully


described in probability terms.  One often cited criterion of


this sort is the minima* decision criterion of Wald [24]where


(in our context) the householder is presumed to know with zero


probability of error that future air pollution dosages will fall


within a given range.  The sufferer's objective is then to make


his maximum possible loss as small as possible, where the loss is


defined in terms of the discrepancy between the realized


consequence of an act and the utility which would have been


obtained if the future state of nature had been correctly forecast.


As Hildreth [25] notes, the common sense appeal of a criterion


of this sort depends directly on how small this maximum possible


loss can be made.  If this maximum possible loss is likely to be


small relative to the costs of acquiring that information



-------
                                -27-



for air pollution situations even when increased risks of health


effects are accounted for -- then the criterion would appear to

be reasonable.  If, for example, with wide fluctuations in air

pollution dosages and damages a sufferer employing this criterion

can come within $100 of his minimum possible losses under perfect
                                •
certainty, then the criterion might arouse the sufferer's interest.

But if the discrepency results in his death or even damages of

$1000 he might display no interest whatsoever.

     The article of Hildreth [25] referred to above derives an


expression from a Cobb-Douglas production function for a firm's


demand for an input where the firm employs a minimax decision

criterion.  A somewhat more general development applicable to

the minimax decision criterion of an air pollution sufferer can

be obtained with the aid of some easily interpreted diagraramatics.

     Assume that the sufferer acts as if air pollution dosages

over whatever time period is deemed relevant are bounded above

and below by fixed values.  Let U(p+) in Figure 1 represent the

upper bound of these dosages and U(p-) the lower bound.  The

householder would act as if any dosage, p, in the interval

(u(p+), U(p-)l could occur.  Since  3U/9 p < 0, movement up the U

axis represents increasing utility levels and decreasing air

pollution dosages.  From the sufferer's point of view, any


-------
                                -28-



increase in dosages is presumed to be utterly independent of any


activities the sufferer might undertake.  Thus on the U axis, each


utility level is associated with a unique dosage of air pollutants


over whose presence or absence the sufferer knows he can exercise


no influence.


     With any given level of air pollution dosages, there can be
                               t

combined various quantities of ei bundle, z, of housing characteristics.


The additional utility to be obtained at a given dosage level


with the consumption of an additional unit of the bundle of housing


characteristics is given by  dUi/d z, i - 1, 2, 3.  The marginal


costs and average costs of obtaining an additional unit of the


bundle of housing characteristics are given respectively by


 dc/3 z and c/r.  As before, a one to one correspondence is


assumed between utility and dollars.  The increasing  9U/3  z


associated with declining pollution dosages implies that


pollution affects the utility obtainable from the elements of


the bundle of housing characteristics.  The sufferer's problem


is to select that quantity of the bundle of housing


characteristics minimizing his maximum possible loss from air


pollution dosages.


     Temporarily assume the householder acts as if the pollution


dosage to which he will be subjected is to be p where p lies



-------
                                  -29-
Figure 1.  Possible Householder Losses from Errors in Forecasting

-------
                                -30-






z units of the bundle of housing characteristics, where z is



someplace in the interval Jz+, z-1 .  If p+ rather than p is



ultimately realized, the householder has purchased ab = z+z units



of the bundle of housing characteristics whose cost outweighs the



additional utility these units provide him.  This total loss is



represented by the area a e b.  On the other hand, if p- rather



than p is ultimately realized, the householder has failed to



consume fg = zz- units of the bundle of housing characteristics



whose cost does not outweigh the additional utility these units



could have provided him.  The loss he suffers by overestimating



future pollution dosages is given by the area e f g.  Clearly,



the rainimax rule amounts to selecting a p such that the quantity



of the bundle of housing characteristics associated with that p



is expected to result in a b e - e f g.  Thus the minimax



pollution dosage to expect is a function of the maximum and the



minimum expected dosages and the costs of obtaining additional



units of the bundle of housing characteristics.



     It is interesting to compare the damage implications of the



householder's use of a minimax criterion with the implications



when an expected utility criterion is employed.  Assuming for



simplicity that only the first moment of the air pollution density



function is relevant, the expected utility criterion leads to a




-------
                                -31-




with information p-f, p- uses the minimax criterion but with


additional information might switch to the expected utility


criterion.  Now assume that if he had this additional information,


the mean of the probability distribution of future dosages would


prove to be j>, the midrange of the interval/p+, p-J  Thus


E(U) =  E [E(p)l = f(p) with the additional information.  Given


these assumptions, it is easily seen with the aid of the diagrams


in Figure 2 that the quantity consumed of the bundle of


characteristics and thus the losses due to any errors in forecasting


pollution dosages are Identical regardless of the decision criterion


employed only when  9c/3 z is linear.  Otherwise, the loss will

                                3     3
differ according to the sign of 3 c/9 z  and the magnitude of the


ultimately realized pollution dosage.  In other words, the losses


householders suffer due to uncertainty about future air pollution


dosages can be the joint result of their expectations about these


dosages and their decision criteria under conditions of uncertainty.




     The Formation of Air Pollution Dosage Expectations.  From the


immediately preceding material on decision criteria, it is


apparent that householder damages from air pollution dosages are


by no means independent of the accuracy with which expectations about future


dosages are formed.  That is, realized householder damages



-------
 u  *
-32-
u   .
Figure 2.  Comparison of Minimax z, z', and Expected Utility z, z,

-------
                                -33-






householder predictions.  Realized damages are but present




representations of positions taken in the past in response to




expected air pollution dosages.




     It seems likely that the householder will act as a more or




less passive observer of air pollution events.  He can have little




knowledge of future events other than the inferences he can draw



from already realized events, for an active search by him for




information on future events is likely to be far too costly.




This cost could be less if the planned emissions of pollution




perpetrators were not entirely independent of individual




householder decisions.  It would also be less if ambient air




standards were imposed with some stringency or if distinct



contingent claims markets in air pollution events were available




for the individual receptor.  The scale economies of information




production and risk-spreading characteristics of these markets



could make information about future air pollution events much




less costly to the individual householder.  Though contingent




claims markets do in fact exist for durable assets affected by




air pollution, e.g., life, medical, and property insurance, the




householder must still make the costly .effort to distinguish



between air pollution risk's contribution to premiums and the




contribution of other risks.  Thus in spite of the losses





-------
                                -34-




dosages when purchasing a residential property (moving or


selling is costly, particularly if done a year or two after


purchase), the seemingly even higher costs of most alternative


informational sources on future air pollution events make


predictions based almost entirely on realized dosages economically


viable.   It is therefore a reasonable approximation to assume,


as this study shall, that the major and perhaps the only argument


in the householder expectation generating function is some history


of realized air pollustion dosages.


     With one unsuccessful exception [3, pp. 141-151 1, previous


studies of the covariation between air pollution and urban


residential real estate values have been strictly cross-sectional.


That is, observations have been assumed to be drawn from time periods


having similar initial and terminal dates and in which the


effects of time's passage are presumed to be neutral.  A dynamic


stability has been assumed in which according to Samuelson


[9, p.26lj ". . .from any initial conditions all the variables


approach their equilibrium values in the limit as time becomes


infinite, i.e.,

                          0
            lim x (t) =• xt
             t -*• »


regardless of the initial conditions."  This means that the


difference between the ultimately realized or equilibrium value



-------
                                -35-






for a sufficiently long interval of time, t, and that this




difference tends to zero as it becomes large.  The present essay




is also strictly cross-sectional.  However, in previous studies,




large has come to mean an annual average of air pollution dosages




for whatever single twelve or eighteen month period for which




the investigators happened to possess air pollution observations.



The expectations about air pollution dosages, on the basis of




which economic adjustments to the presence of air pollution are




made, are presumed to be formed solely within the single year




for which information on dosages is available.  In some studies




the result has been that the expectations implicit in property




values are assumed to have been formed on the basis of air




pollution not occurring until anywhere from four to seven years




later!  In addition to the possibility of introducing some




statistical biases, this assumes what would seem an inordinate



amount of prescience in the residential property market.




     As earlier noted, a more appealing hypothesis is that



expectations about future air pollution dosages adapt to changes



in present air pollution dosages only after some lag in time; so



that if such a change has any permanent effect at all, the



effect is not registered all at once over a fairly short interval




of time but it instead distributed over several time periods.





-------
                                -36-


only of air pollution dosages,

(26)         cik = a± + bE/ J m k   pltdt + uik   (i - l,...,n)

where a and b are coefficients to be estimated, c is the
                                     m
property's current market value,   E/t»k  p-ttdt is the expectation
of the stream of air pollution dosages at the ith property at the

end of the current period k, and u is an error term.  All variables

are expressed in logarithms throughout.  In order to make (26)

tractable in terms of the standard analysis of distributed lags,

we assume

(27)         plt =  f (E/ t-k  pltdt)
       *
where p^t is an observable scalar quantity of air pollution

dosages.  Expected values of this scalar quantity of air pollution

dosages can be related to observable values by specifying an

expectation generating function such as

(28)         E(p*t +1) - ECpJt) =   x[Pit - E (Pit -1 >]

or

(28a)        E(plt +1) -  xptt  +  (1 - A )  E(pit _x )

This states that air pollution dosage expectations are revised

in proportion to the error associated with previous levels of
             12
expectations.

     If (28a) is linear in logarithms, A. can be interpreted as an

elasticity coefficient showing the responsiveness of current


-------
dosages and  the dosages expected in the previous period for the



current period.   In the case where the coefficient is unity, air



pollution damages as registered in the offer prices for bundles  '



of housing characteristics are simply a function of current dosages.



That  is, if dosages were previously expected to remain constant, '



implying that property values were at long-run equilibrium levels,



they  are now expected to remain constant, at the level of current



dosages.  A new long-run equilibrium in the property market is



therefore established.  In contrast, an elasticity coefficient   j



of zero implies that changes in current dosages have no effect



upon  the property market's existing long-run equilibrium.  Changes



in current dosages have no effect upon future dosages.



      The expression (28a) can be solved for expected dosages as



a function of m (m   0) past values of realized dosages.

                *             *              *                2  *

(29)         E(pit + i) - At pit + (1 - \±) Pit - 1 + (1 - V  Pit - 2


                                       i  m   *
                          + ... + (1 . A£)   Pit - m



which reduces to



(30)  .       E( Pit + i) -  Ai    *      (1 - Ai)t  plt _ m.



                                  t - k



This  is simply a moving average with geometrically declining



weights on past values of p*.  Muth [ill has demonstrated that



(30) minimizes the mean square error in forecasts of dosages if




-------
                                 -38-

 realizsd  dosages  are  first-order moving averages of random

 deviates . Even when  the changes caused by the process are not

 a  first-order moving  average of  random deviates so that mean

 square  error of forecasts is not minimized, Cox [12] shows that

 (30) may  still be a highly efficient predictor of realized

 dosages.

     Making the obvious substitution of (30) into (26), the

 cumulative effect upon property values of a change in realized

 dosages under our assumptions is

 (31)         cik  = ai + b  At   *     (1 . Xj* p*t . m + uik
                                 t=k

 if and only if 0  <. X± <_ 1.

 The Empirical Background

     General Nature of the Data.  The city from which the data

 used in this study come is Chicago, Illinois, a city which,

 according to Babcock  [31]  , possesses the distinction of having

 the dirtiest air  of any large city in the United States.

 Histories of monthly  ambient air concentrations of suspended

 particulates and  sulfur dioxide at twenty or fewer sampling

 stations were provided by the Chicago Air Pollution Control

District  for each month from January, 1964, through December,

 1967.  A history  of average annual dustfalls was obtained for each


-------
                                -39-


sampling stations ig given by the circled capital letters on the
                                i
city map of Figure 3.

     The air pollution data were combined with.data on 1288

individual single family residential property transactions

whose mortgages had been insured by the Federal Housing

Administration over the January, 1964 - December, 1967 interval.

A rough idea of the approximate locations of these transactions

is given by the dotted lines of Figure 3.  The small arrows

found occassionally on these lines indicate the direction from

the line in which the transactions are to be found.  A clear

majority of the transactions are on the city's south side.

     Excluding transformations, 297 distinct bits of information

on the air pollution history and the transaction, buyer,

improvement, site, and neighborhood characteristics were collected

for each individual transaction.  In the original FHA records,

the individual transactions were grouped only by the time of

their entry into these records.  Assuming a more or less constant

lag between time of sale and entry into the records, the

observations were thus originally grouped by a sequence of dates.

From this population, an initial sampling selected every third

entry.  In a subsequent sampling every fifth remaining record was

taken.  The FHA records ultimately used for this analysis thus


-------
                                     -Uo-
Figure 3.  Locations of
           Air Pollution
           Monitoring
           Stations and
           Property

-------
                                -41-



insured by the FHA in the City of Chicago from 1964 through 1967.


The completely disaggregated and highly detailed nature of this data


allows one to ascertain whether the several possible sources of


statistical bias present in previous studies might indeed be


actual.


     The Air Pollution Data.  Perhaps the major advantage offered


by the detailed nature of the data is the relative (relative to


that of previous studies) fineness with which air pollution


dosages at each residential location could be determined.  For


example, the air pollution data employed in Anderson and Crocker


[ l] were taken from rather crude isopleth maps of the cities

                                           t
studied and transferred by hand to census tract maps.  The


isopleths distinguished only between four or five broad intervals


of air pollution dosages and the uppermost interval was unbounded


in the real numbers.  Thus the lower bound of each interval had to


be employed as the scalar quantity of air pollution dosages.  An


interval's lower bound was assigned to a census tract by "eyeballing"


the overlay of the isopleth map upon the tract map in order to


ascertain whether more than half the tract was located inside or


outside a particular interval's isopleth.


     In the present study, the raw data from each of the Chicago


Air Pollution Control District's twenty sampling stations



-------
                                -42-






per billion by volume per day and suspended particulates in




micrograms per cubic meter per day.  According to Stanley




  [37, p.  7 ]  , these means were constructed from daily arithmetic




means of  three day sampling periods at each of the twenty




sampling  stations.  Dustfall measures were provided in terms of




annual arithmetic means of the basic sampling unit, monthly tons



                11
per square mile.''  Table 1 presents the annual arithmetic means




from 1964 through 1967 for sulfur dioxide and suspended




particulates at each of the twenty sampling stations.  It should




be noted  that the records are not complete on a month by month




basis for each and every sampling station.  Dustfall is




disregarded in Table 1, as it will be henceforth, since in the



empirical analysis its presence did not yield any estimates



amenable  to economic interpretation or statistical inference.




     Employing the above data, and assuming equal variances in the




monthly air pollution distribution from one year to another at




each of the twenty sampling stations, the hypothesis was tested




by means of the "t-test"that the distributions for every year




at any given sampling station were drawn from the same




population.  In addition, an "F-test" was applied to each set of



distributions at each station to test that assumption of equal




variances among distributions required for the validity of the




-------
                                -43-



 Table  1.   Annual AriChmeCic Mean Pollutant Dosages by Station and Year
Station Sulfur Diox

A
B
C
D

F
C
H

I
J
K
L
M

N

0

P

Q
R
T
W
V
1964
SO3
80
503
80
a
170
70
iooa

60
40
50
120
203
a
20
a
40
a
40
a
40
20
1303
203

1965
31
79
36
76

102
65
78
b
53
43
46
92
25

32

20

20

33
21
71
38

.de* ;Sus
1966
34
66
28
55

73
64
83
c
52
42
50
90
44

54

33

39

38
37
71
57

1967
26
53
26
23

82
56d
71e
f

35
40
68
42

45

25

24

28
24
59
44

196.4
94
134
101
186

178
163
139

157
146
125
173
114

119

132

124

138
123
124
1348
142g
ended Particulates**
1965
98
128
100
166

173
155
135

146
132
127
164
112

117

125

118

147
130
118
130
147
1966
100
132
111
175

174
165
143

176
147
136
177
125

127

145

131

156
135
144
138
162
1967
82
117
93
167

172
142
132
f

132
118
147
113

115

133

117

142
128
125
120
139
Source:  Chicago Air Pollution Control  District




        *In parts per billion by volume per twenty-four hours.




       **In micrograras per cubic meter  per twenty-four hours.




       a)Does not include January 1  through September 30.




       b)Does not include November 1 through November 30.




       c)Does not include October 1  through December 31.




       d)Does not include February 1 through March  31.




       e)Does not include June 1 through July 31.



       f)No data available.





-------
                                -44-


stations having complete monthly records for at least two calendar

years in the 1964-67 period.  Table 2 below shows by pairs of
                                           I
calendar years for those stations having complete monthly records

the number of stations whose means and variances exhibited

statistically significant differences at the .05 levels of the

two-tailed t-test and the F-test.  The column labeled n

indicates the number of complete record stations, t indicates the

number of complete record stations not having equal means by the

t-tcst, F  is the number of complete record stations not having

equal variances by the F-test, and t & !F is the number of complete

record stations appearing in t and F simultaneously.  From Table 2

it would appear that only 1966 and 1967 exhibit statistically

significant differences in dosages of suspended particulates at a

substantial number of stations.  However, except for 1964 and

1965, a fair number of stations have significant differences in

sulfur dioxide dosages for each possible pair of years.  Given that

suspended particulates and sulfur dioxide have widely recognized

synergic properties, the results in Table 2 provide fairly strong

grounds for asserting that air pollution dosages did display

substantial variation from year to year during the 1964-67 time

interval.  A causal inspection of the spatial distribution of


-------
                                -45-






air pollution sampling stations gave no cause to assert that  the




air pollution dosages at the residential locations behaved  any




differently than those at the station locations.






Table 2.  Stations Having Differences in Animal Air Pollution Distributions
Years
Sulfur Dioxide
Suspended Particulates

1964/65
1964/66
1964/67
1965/66
1965/67
1966/67
n
7
7
6
18
15
15
t
<—>••••••
1
4
3
9
5
6
. F .
0
1
1
2
2
1
t&F
«••*«•••••
0
1
1
1
0
0
n
18
17
17
19
19
19
t
0
0
2
3
1
11
F
2
0
2
0
0
0
t&F
0
0
0
0
0
0
     The data on month by month suspended particulate and  sulfur




dioxide dosages at each sampling station were used to calculate




similar dosages at each sample residential location.   The




calculations finally employed in the empirical analysis of air




pollution damages were made separately for each of the two




pollutants according to the following expression:
1*
E
2
i=l
Di
Pi
i=l Di

4
I
4
Z


-------
                                 -46-





 where p is the calculated arithmetic mean monthly dosage of



 suspended particulates or sulfur dioxide at a. specific  sample



 residential location,  D.  is  the  distance from the location  to  the



 ith air pollution sampling station, and  p^  is the pollution



 dosage registered at  the  ith sampling  station.   Stations used  for



 this calculation were  selected so as to  enclose  the  residential



 location in question.   No more than four stations were  ever used



 for this purpo.se.   The calculated residential location  dosage, p,



 therefore amounts to a weighted  index  of suspended particulates



 or  sulfur dioxide,  with the  weight consisting solely of straight



 line distances  from the residential location to  each of no  less



 than three and  no more than  four sampling stations.  No attempt



 was made to account for variations in meteorology, topography, or



 other factors which could  contribute to  differences  in  pollution


                                                            14
 dosages  between sampling  stations and  residential  locations.



 The nature of the measurement error, if  any,  introduced by



 failing  to account  for these factors is  unknown.



      Simultaneity of Air Pollution and Transactions  Data.  The



 relative  crudeness  of  the air pollution measures  employed in



 previous  studies has not been limited solely  to  the  use of broad



dosage intervals.  As was earlier noted, this relative crudity



has  extended to attempts to  explain differential property values




-------
                                -47-






number of years.  In Anderson and Crocker til, it is shown under




fairly weak conditions that such discrepancies can cause the




negative influence of air pollution  dosages to be understated. ;




Clearly, there is no reason to think that the air pollution




dosages to which householders in year t are responding necessarily




correspond to the dosages prevailing in t + m  (m > 0).  There




is no reason to think that the householders at a given location




were the same in the two sets of years, nor is there any reason




why the air pollution dosages must be the same.  If the marginal



air pollution damage function is not constant over increasing




dosages or if locations are assigned among householders on the




basis of relative air pollution sensitivities, any change in



absolute or relative dosage magnitudes from t to t + m gives




cause for a good deal of scepticism about the meaningfulness of




estimates.  The data available to the present study allow me to




ascertain whether such scepticism is justified, since disaggregated




property value data for any one of four years can be combined with




air pollution data for any one of four years.



     Aggregation Bias.  The possibility of measurement error has




been present in the transactions data used in previous studies as



well as in the air pollution data.  With the sole exception of




Ridker's inconclusive study [3, pp. 141-151 J, previous studies





-------
                                 -48-






property  values have exclusively employed census tracts as  the




fundamental unit  of observation.  Tract boundaries usually  contain




within  them at least several hundred housing units.  These  areas,




according to  the  compilers of the census [32, p.l ], are supposed




to be relatively  uniform with respect to population characteristics,



economic  status,  and living conditions, so that measures of central




tendency  for  the  individual tracts presumably characterize  closely




all units in  the  tract.  In the  empirical analysis, group averages




of residential unit values are customarily regressed upon group




averages  of the residents*, residential units', and tract's characteristics,




The aggregation thus precedes analysis and the researcher therefore




has had no basis  upon which to evaluate the tolerability of any



bias which the aggregation may introduce.  Of necessity, it has




been assumed  that a knowledge of the aggregate relation (the




function  relating the aggregates) leads to the same value of the




dependent  variable (offer price) as does a knowledge of the




disaggregated relation.




     Aggregation  bias can arise because the assumption of




considerable homogeneity among the residents and residential




locations within  a single census tract may in fact not be




fulfilled, and because the air pollution dosages to which each



residential location is subjected may not be linearly related to





-------
                                -49-



Assumc  the disaggregated offer function for bundles of housing
                                                                 t
                                                                 t
characteristics is given by                                      |


(1)          cij = ai + bipij + uij          i  =  l>-">n
                                             j  =  1 » • • • »r
                                             n     r

where i refers to residential location, j to census tracts, a and

b are coefficients to be estimated, and u is an error term having

the customary properties.  For simplicity, we assume that air

pollution, p, is the only argument of offer price, c, which differs

across residential locations.

     Average tract offer prices and pollution dosages are clearly
                     n                              n

(2)                  I   Ci,                        *
              C4. _i=! _ - _ ' and  P,-   _i=!
               J           n                  J          n


Under aggregation, the  intercept and the error term are
                    n                          n
(3)                 I     a                    ^
                                        u
                        n                          n


The aggregate relation is therefore


(4)          C. = a + bP. + u


where b, the coefficient of P.,, is apparently

                   I     b<
(5)          b „  1-1     £   .
                       n


In other words, the average offer price depends on the pollution


dosages suffered by the tract's n residential locations.  This



-------
                                -50-


linear and Includes an error term whose expected  value is  zero

for all Cjj.  Disregarding a and u * , note,  however,  that both

b and P  are aggregated.  Thus
       ^             n                   n               n
(6)                  E     b    .         l  .  P.         I
              bP   .
                                         l .  Pl.
                                        j-i    J
                j         n                  n              n

Therefore

(7)                z    b
-------
                                -51-



whose sensitivity is less than a census tract's average.  In this

latter case, however, the coefficient in (4) would be biased

toward zero.  The conclusion is the rather dismaying one that the

measure of air pollution dosages in those studies employing the  i

census tract as the fundamental unit of observation has differed


from one census tract to another.  There could conceivably have

been as many unique measures employed as there are census tracts.
                                                                 i
The simultaneous availability  to this study of disaggregated    |

FHA data and census tract data for the City of Chicago enable one

to ascertain the importance in Chicago of this bias.

     Use of Actual Market Sales Prices.  A perhaps somewhat more

mundane advantage of the disaggregated FHA data available to this


study is the presence of the actual market prices at which

transactions were concluded.  Except for rental properties, the

offer prices set forth in the census volumes are defined as

owners' estimates of what their properties would sell for if

offered for sale at the tine of the census.  The errors in these

estimates could be large, though it is generally agreed the errors

are random and on the average tend to be offsetting.  It is

therefore thought that the traditional errors-in-variables

specification yields reliable estimates, particularly when some

prior aggregation occurs on the basis of census tracts.  Nevertheless,


-------
                                -52-






solitary 1954 article by Klsh and Lansing [33] which showed that




owners' estimates of offer prices in the 1950 census exhibited




random variation around the "true" assessed values.  Though the




data employed in the present study can neither confirm nor deny




this finding, they do provide the opportunity to avoid such




errors as may be present in the census responses.




     Possibilities in the Use of Assessed Property Values.  In




spite of the extent to which previous studies have depended on it,




census data is, of course,not the only readily available




information on the offer prices for and the components of various




bundles of housing characteristics.  In particular, a vast




storehouse of information of this sort is readily available in




the property tax assessment records of nearly every  municipality




in the country.  Its usefulness for the problem being studied




here hinges largely upon the linearity of the relation between



the weights assessed valuations assign air pollution dosages and




the weights actual market valuations assign them.  If there is a




linear relation between these weights, then assessment records




could validly by employed for determining air pollution damages




to residential properties.  The presence in the FHA data of annual



property taxes as well as actual market prices for each residential




property observation permits a test of this hypothesis for the





-------
                                -53-




value for each observation permits a similar test between this




assessed value and actual market price.  In this last case, if no




significant differences are apparent, one could conceivably use




some combination of FHA assessed values and tax assessment




records to estimate air pollution damages to residential properties.




     Miscellaneous Advantages of the FHA Data.  Finally, the




extremely detailed nature of the disaggregated FHA data introduces




a further but rather disconnected set of advantages.  First, the




availability of data on residential property maintenance costs




provides a basis for comparisons with the results obtained in




Booz, Allen and Hamilton, Inc. [34] , Michelson and Tourin [35 ],




and similar studies.  Second, previous atudies because of data



limitations have had to employ rather crude measures of several




variables which can be expected to determine offer price.  For




example, median number of rooms has been used as a measure of




available housing space, number of housing units per acre as a




measure of lot size, and the number of housing units older than




some arbitrarily specified age as a measure of the age of site



improvements.  It can be shown, e.g., Goldberger [36, pp. 284-286 ],




that unless the proxies are contemporaneously uncorrelated with




the disturbances but correlated with the true regressors, the




use of a proxy can introduce an asymptotic bias into estimates.




Except for permanent resident income, the great detail in which





-------
                                -54-






USP of any proxies.  Finally, the available detail and number




of observations allows the partition of the sample on the basis




of factors which might reflect differential responses to air




pollution dosages.  Thus one might expect and therefore test for




differential responses to similar air pollution dosages by




resident income, age of improvements, and neighborhood characteristics,



for example.




The Variables




     As earlier noted, information was collected on an extremely




wide variety of factors which are measures of and influences upon




offer prices for bundles of housing characteristics.  Presented




below are exact definitions of those measures of offer prices and




those explanatory variables which appear in the ordinary least



squares regressions reported in the next section.  Inclusion of




variables for which information was available but which are not




defined below did not ever change appreciably any of the next




section's results.  Furthermore, the coefficients for those



variables not defined here were almost uniformly nonsignificant.^




     Dependent Variables.  Seven dependent variables are to be




used in this study.  Unless otherwise noted, all are defined in



accordance with standard FHA definitions .




     COSTS is the sale price of the residential property plus





-------
                                -55-






are borne by the purchaser.  It is equivalent to the mortgage




amount plus the mortgagor's actual cash outlay.  The inclusion




of these incidental costs is entirely consistent with our view




of goods as generating housing characteristics.  For example, the




improvement in tenure security to which a costly title search




contributes can be a valued characteristic of the residential




property.




     PSITE is the FHA-estimated market price of the site.




Neighborhood characteristics, street improvements, utilities,




rough grading, terracing walls, and retaining walls are all




included as part of the site.




     FHAVL is the "FHA-estimated price that typical buyers would




be warranted in paying for the (whole)  property for long-term




use or investment."




     MAINT is the "FHA-estimated average yearly cost of




maintaining the physical elements of the property to prevent




acceleration of deterioration, and to assure safe and comfortable




living conditions."




     TAXES includes annual property taxes and any continuing




nonrepayable special assessments, as estimated by the FHA.  These




taxes are thus the result of Chicago's assessment ratio and the




property tax rate per thousand dollars of assessed valuation.  In





-------
                                -56-






median assessment ratio  (gross assessed value as a percentage of




market value) was 35.80  percent and its median nominal property




tax  rate  (annual tax billed as a percentage of taxable assessed




value) was 5.43 percent.




     MVAL6, as defined by the Census Bureau [32, p. 7 ], is the




median of the owners' estimates on each census tract of what




their properties would sell for if offered for sale in April,




1960.




     MVL66, according to De Vise [44, pp. 151-152 ], is the




"average value of homes'* in 1966 in each "community area" of




Chicago.  A community area is a collection of several census




tracts.  No indication of how MVL66 was established could be




discovered.  A reasonable but vague guess would be that it is




some simple extrapolation of 1960 census figures combined with a




more or less intuitive knowledge of community area trends between



1960 and 1966.




     explanatory Variables.  The list of explanatory variables




used at one point or another in the next section is long.  An




effort to justify in detail the use of each of these variables




could require several separate essays.  The justification for the



use of each variable is therefore limited to a very short




explanation of the sign one can expect for its coefficient and,




-------
                                -57-



can be expected to vary with variations in dependent variables.


A  few references where more thorough explanations of the


variables'  behavior can be found are offered.  Unless otherwise v


noted, all variables are defined in accordance with standard


FHA definitions.  Statements about the sign:? coefficients can be


expected to  assume refer to offer price as a dependent variable.


When other dependent variables are relevant, explicit note will  '<

                                                                 I
be taken.  In order to facilitate reference, the explanations


are presented in the alphabetical order of the acronyms assigned


the variables.


     ALMNM is a dummy variable having a value of one if the major


living unit upon the residential property has aluminum siding and


zero otherwise.  This variable was employed only to explain the


variation in maintenance costs.  If advertisements of the


aluminum industry are to be believed, aluminum's properties are


such that maintenance costs are less relative to alternative


types of siding.


     BLK66 is the percentage of total population that was black


in a community area as of April, 1966.  This variable, the data


source for which is De Vise [44, pp. 145-146] , was used to


partition the disaggregated FHA data and as an explanatory


variable when MVL66 was employed as a dependent variable.  As is



-------
                                -58-




variable  Is not at all clear; nor is the meaning of the coefficient




itself.   Under some assumptions, a positive sign attached to a




statistically significant coefficient can be taken as evidence




of housing discrimination.




     BRICK is a dummy variable having a value of one if a brick




frame it employed to support the floors and roof of the major



improvement upon a residential location and zero if not.  This




variable was used only when maintenance costs were the dependent




variable.  Since factory fabricated frames are the type of frame




for which no variable is provided, it is probably the case that




BRICK will take on a negative sign where MAINT is the dependent




variable.




     CRIMX is an index of the rate of commitment to prison of




male community area residents from 1963 through 1966.  The index,




which was taken from Shaw and McKay [52, p. 355],is the four year




rate in the community area divided by the mean four year rate for




the Chicago metropolitan area.  If the probability of criminal




attacks against one's person or property increases with the




absolute number of criminal offenders inhabiting one's




neighborhood, then the coefficient for this variable must take on




a negative sign.  Or, even if criminal offenders carry out their




activities beyond the neighborhood, they may have life styles





-------
                                -59-






     DILP6 is the proportion of all residential units in a




census  tract classed as dilapidated in 1960.  This variable, as




was noted in Anderson and Crocker flK is  a  composite




of a neighborhood's physical appearance and the attitudes of its




inhabitants about that appearance.  Its influence upon offer price




is clearly negative.




     OISSM is the distance in tenths of miles to the intersection




of State and Madison Streets in the Loop area of downtown Chicago.




Given that the disamenities of residential locations near the




center of the city don't outweigh the savings in travel and




communication costs, the coefficient for the variable must be




negative.




     DLAKE represents the distance in tenths of miles of the




residential location from Lake Michigan.  Since this lake is




widely acknowledged to be one of Chicago's prime esthetic and




climatic amenities, the coefficient for this variable will be




negative.




     DTTYP is a dummy variable having a value of one if the major




living unit was completely detached from any other living unit




and zero otherwise.  The sign for the coefficient for this




variable is expected to be positive, given that a nondetached    ,




structure offers less privacy and requires agreement with





-------
                                -60-






characteristics can be undertaken.




     FRAME  is a dummy variable having a value of one if a wooden




frame  is employed to support the floors and the roof and zero if




not.   Given  that wooden frames typically cost more to maintain




and have shorter expected lives than  most other frames, the




coefficient  for this variable is expected to be negative in sign.




     USAGE  is the age in calendar years of the major living unit




at the residential location.  It was calculated as the difference




between the  year of sale and the year in which the major living




unit was built.  Because of depreciation and obsolescence, the




coefficient  for this variable is expected to be negative.  It is




generally acknowledged by most writers on housing, e.g., Grigsby




[45] , that  rates of depreciation and obsolescence tend to decline




with age.




     INCM6 is the median family income on'a census tract in April,




1960.  Given that bundles of housing characteristics are not




inferior goods, the sign of the coefficient for this variable




must be positive.  Since each observation of this variable is a




measure of central tendency, it is probably a fair measure of




permanent income.




     INC66 is the "average income" in April, 1966, in each




residential  location's community area.  Since a community area





-------
                                -61-






made up of a broad and heterogeneous collection of occupational




groups who, when considered together, have transitory incomes




averaging out to zero.  This measure of income, given that it    <_




does not contain other sources of measurement error, should thus




be better than INCM6 as a measure of permanent income.




     INDUT is the hundredths of square miles devoted to industrial




uses within the square mile whose center is the residential




location.  Data for this variable was obtained from maps published




in the several volumes by the Chicago Department of Development




and Planning [54] .  The variable is intended to account for the




presumed disamenities of noise, unsightliness, etc., of residing




adjacent to or within an industrial area.  Dirt disamenities are




registered in the air pollution variable.  If expectations of a




shift of residential uses to industrial uses are not predominant,




this variable has a depressing effect upon offer price.  Partitioning




the sample by this variable permits the consideration of the




effects of air pollution in areas where the confounding influences




of industrial disamenities other than air pollution are minor.




     LIVAR is "the total square foot area of a house appropriately




improved for the intended use and in compliance with the minimum




property standards for new homes and with generally accepted     ;




criteria for existing homes.  It includes family rooms, improved




recreation and attic rooms, cantilevered overhang of rooms and





-------
                                -62-






 spacc  permits a greater variety of activities and houses a




 greater number of people.  The sign of  the variable's coefficient




 can  therefore be expected to be positive.




     LOTSZ  is simply the number of square feet in the lot.  Since




 greater lot size permits a greater variety of positively valued




 activities  to be undertaken, the covariation between offer price




 and  lot size should be positive.  Alonso [ 28]  and Muth [ 27 ]




 devote substantial energies to the explanation of the theoretical




 significance of this variable in markets for bundles of housing




 characteristics.  No information was available for this variable




 in the 1964 disaggregated FHA d.ita.




     MASON  is another dummy variable.  This variable has a value




 of one if the frame of the major improvement at the residential




 location is masonry and zero if not.  Its proper sign where




 factory fabricated frames are excluded has not been investigated




 by the writer.




     MODUR  is the term of the mortgage in years.  All mortgages in




 this study appeared to be of the straight term type such that the




mortgagor pays a fixed sum toward principal and interest each




month.  The cost per dollar of the mortgage to the mortgagor is




viewed as the discounted value of his future interest payments




 less the discounted expected value of the asset he possesses





-------
                                -63-



 if  the mortgagor's subjective rate of interest is greater than


 the mortgage rate of interest will the mortgage actually be


 taken out.  Thus, either an increase in the mortgage term or a


 decrease in the mortgage rate of interest would reduce the costs


 of  purchasing bundles of housing characteristics relative to the


 costs of purchasing alternative characteristics bundles.  The
                                                                 i
 quantities demanded of and offer prices for housing bundles


 would therefore increase.  In the present study, market interest


 rates were almost completely invariant for the sample within any


 one year and, for that matter, did not change greatly over the


 four year period being considered.  Accordingly, only mortgage


 duration, whose sign is expected to be positive, is employed as


 an explanatory variable.


     At this point, two peculiarities of FHA-insured mortgage


 loans relative to conventional mortgage loans should be recognized,


 First, the FHA requires that issuers of FHA-insured notes receive


 cash payments equal to the full face value of the note.  That is,


 the cash payment cannot register any discount or premium which


may be attached to a note when the note specifies a rate of


 interest below or above the prevailing market rate of interest.


 If, for example, a discount is in order, the mortgagor absorbs it


because the seller inflates the price of the house by an amount



-------
                                -64-






the note.  Therefore to the extent that interest rates on FHA




loans in Chicago from 1964 through 1967 were less than those on




conventional loans, the observed price of a given bundle of




housing characteristics in this study's data would be greater




than the observed price of a similar housing bundle financed by




a conventional loan.  A cursory survey of prevailing rates during




the period makes it appear that FHA rates after 1965 were about




one-half of one percent less than those for conventional loans.




Thus, for a given bundle of housing characteristics, the absolute




magnitudes of marginal changes in the original values of the




explanatory variables in this study's results are somewhat




greater than would be the case if the house purchase was financed



by a conventional loan.  In particular, the absolute magnitudes




of the marginal damages are somewhat greater.




     The above tendency is reenforced by the fact that FHA-insured




loans typically have only a small or nonexistent prepayment




penalty', whereas conventional loans often have penalties amounting




to as much as six months' interest.  One would expect the positive




value of the lack of an FHA prepayment penalty to be capitalized




into the sale price of the property.  However, it must be



emphasized that neither this peculiarity nor that pointed out in



the previous paragraph introduce a statistical bias to our





-------
                                -65-






property sold on FHA terms, but some slight downward revision




must be made in the absolute magnitudes of the marginal damage




estimates obtained from the disaggregated FHA data if inferences




are to be made about properties sold on conventional terms.




     NHAGE is the average age of the residential properties in




the 160 acre quarter section in which the residence is located.




Values for this variable were calculated from Olcutt & Co. [53]  |




where typical ages in each quarter section are presented.  In




cases where more than one typical age was presented, the weight




each ago. received was the inverse of the number of "typical" ages.




Given that bundles of housing characteristics generally provide




less utility as they age, the demand for these bundles tends to




decline.  Price thus decreases and by the filtering process the




bundles are thought to become available to households having




relatively low incomes.  This variable for the disaggregated




FHA data is therefore a representation of the same phenomena as




DILP6 is for the census data.




     NWPP6 is the percentage of total population that was




non-white in census tract as of April, 1960.  As was explained




for BLK66, the meaning of the coefficients obtained for this




variable is not clear.




     OLDER is the percentage of residential units in a census





-------
                                -66-






as a measure of  Che same phenomenon as HSAGE   is  in the disaggregated




FHA data.




     PMM refers  to the minimum arithmetic mean monthly dosage



during a given year of suspended particulates in micrograms per




cubic meter per  twenty-four hours.  As is the case for all the




air pollution variables, the two digits following the acronym




refer to the year in which the air pollution dosages occurred.




Thus, PMM64 is the minimum arithmetic monthly mean dosage of




suspended particulates in 1964.




     PMX is the maximum arithmetic mean monthly dosage during a




given year of suspended particulates.




     PRT is the annual arithmetic mean monthly dosage of suspended




particulates during a given year.




     PSK is the  third statistical moment or skewness of the




distribution of arithmetic mean monthly suspended  particulate




dosages during a given year divided by the annual  arithmetic mean.




     PVR is the second statistical moment or variance of the




distribution of arithmetic mean monthly suspended  particulate



dosages during a given year divided by the annual  arithmetic mean.




     SMM is the minimum arithmetic mean monthly dosage during a



given year of sulfur dioxide in milligrams per one hundred square




centimeters per twenty-four hours.





-------
                                -67-



dioxide during a given year.


     SQIDX is an index of public elementary school quality in


the residence's school district.  The scale of the index has     s


four factors with the digit 1 representing the highest quality


and 4 the lowest.  The source of the index and the explanation


of its construction is to be found in Havighurst [55, p. 146 ].


Generally speaking, the index is a composite of student performance,
                                                                 i

teacher quality, funding, and similar factors.  If householders


do attach positive utility to "good" schools, this variable's


coefficients will assume negative signs.


     STORY is the number of full stories in the major improvement


at the residential location.  This variable was employed only


when MAINT was the dependent variable.  Its influence upon


MAINT is undefined, and it was included in the MAINT regressions


only because it proved to have a statistically significant


coefficient.


     SSK is the third statistical moment or skewness of the


distribution of arithmetic mean monthly sulfur dioxide dosages


during a given year divided by the annual arithmetic mean dosage.


     SVR is the second statistical moment or variance or the


distribution or arithmetic mean sulfur dioxide dosages during a


given year divided by the annual arithmetic mean.



-------
                                -68-
      k'. d i ring a given year.




     TCINC, defined as the current monthly family income of the




residential property's owners, is the income variable always




employed in the empirical analysis of the next section.  Unfortunately,




it is at best an imperfect proxy for the permanent income measure




properly used as an argument in the offer function for bundles of




housing characteristics.    In broad terms, the use of current




rather than permanent income can bias downward and make




inconsistent the estimate of the positive effect upon offer price




of additional income.  Fundamentally, a measurement error is




introduced because lagged income variables which would affect




offer price are not included as regressors.  If, as seems




reasonable, negative transitory incomes appear more frequently




in groups with low current incomes and if positive transitory




incomes appear more frequently in groups with high current




incomes, then the variance of measured income exceeds that of




permanent income.  Cross-sectional least squares estimates of




the responsiveness of offer price to income that are based upon




current income would therefore exhibit a downward bias.




     The income elasticity estimates appearing in the next




section are generally slightly greater than .30.  This is less




than half the most widely accepted estimate of about .90 found,





-------
                                -69-






 tt nearly duplicates the  .35 cross-sectional estimates for measured




 income  elasticity reported by Reid  [46, p. 9] and Malone  [48]  ,




 and approximates that of  .41 found by Atkinson [49]  .  If FHA-   \




 insured mortgages are more likely to be obtained by better




 "credit risks" and if these individuals have lower measured




 income  elasticities of demand for bundles of housing characteristics




 than does the population  of residential property buyers,  then    :




 such differences as remain between the current income elasticities




 obtained here and elsewhere could be accounted for.




     Measures of what the FHA terms "effective income" — the




 FHA estimate of the household's earning capacity before




deduction for Federal income taxes that is likely to prevail




during  the first third of the mortgage term — are present in the




data.  When these measures of what at first appearance looks




 like permanent income were substituted for current income as




regressors, an income elasticity of about .20 was obtained.  This




 is to be expected since without exception the effective income




measures when viewed as measures of permanent income implied




that the transitory component of current income for 1,288




families was negative!   None of the income elasticity results




reported here are peculiar to the City of Chicago, for similar




results were obtained with disaggregated FHA data in Chicago's





-------
                                 -70-





Faced with  these results, a search was  then undertaken  to find



an  instrumental variable, but no variable could be found which



could reasonably be said to be correlated with permanent incomej
                                                                I


independent of the measurement error admittedly present in



TCINC, and orthogonal to other explanatory variables.



     In and of itself,  the measurement  error involved in TCINC is



of  no particular relevance to this study.  It is of concern only



because such error can  also bias the estimates of the effects of



air pollution dosages upon offer price.  If, for example, permanent



income and damages are  strongly and positively correlated and if



the estimated effect of permanent income is biased downward,



then the air pollution damage estimates will tend to be biased



upward (closer to zero) because least squares procedures will



cause the air pollution coefficients to register some of the



positive impact of permanent income upon offer price.  More or



less economic theoretic arguments, e.g., Crocker [50, pp. 238-243]  ,



appear at several places in the pollution economics literature



purporting to show that air pollution damages and (permanent)



income are positively related.  However, none of the previous



work dealing with the covariation between air pollution dosages



and residential property values perceived any collinearity



between air pollution and permanent income requiring substantial


                                                      18

-------
                                -71-



Furthermore, current and permanent income are quite strongly


and positively correlated.  Thus if one income measure is


collinear with air pollution dosages, it is not unreasonable to j


expect the other to be.  However, employing the Farrar-Glauber


[5]   Lests, no statistically significant collinearity was


apparent between TCINC and the air pollution variables in the


present study.  We therefore proceed as if the admitted bias    '


present in the estimated income coefficients does not affect the


air pollution coefficients.



The Results


     All ordinary least squares regressions reported in this


section are multiplicative.  The coefficients of the explanatory


variables are therefore elasticities showing the percentage


change in the dependent variable associated with a one percent


change in the explanatory variable.   The assumption is made


throughout that the marginal cost of supplying bundles of housing

                                                                 I
characteristics is constant.  We assume unless otherwise noted


that the householder employs an expected utility decision


criterion.


     The wide variety of economic-theoretic and empirical hypotheses


raised in the previous sections makes organization of this section


around a central theme rather difficult.  Accordingly, an attempt



-------
                                -72-






dcal with the estimation problems associated with these




formulations, and only then move on to the less familiar.  That




is, the sequence of the presentation of results in this section




does not march along in lock step fashion with the sequence



of the presentation of the economic-theoretic and statistical




hypotheses of earlier sections.




     Statistical Attributes of the Data.  In order to facilitate




evaluation of the results presented in this section, Table 3




immediately below presents the arithmetic means and standard




deviations (in parentheses) of the original values of all the




variables except the air pollution variables listed in the




previous section.  Table 4 presents the same thing for the



various air pollution variables.  In both tables, the columns




refer to the year in which the property sale occurred.  For




certain of the variables, a column thus provides an idea of




year to year variations in a variable or variables for a given




set of residential locations, while the rows show how a given




variable changes with changes in the set of residential locations.




Table 5 presents simple correlation coefficients for the natural




logarithms of some of the variables playing an important role




-------
                                       -73-


Table 3.  Arithmetic Means and Standard Deviations of Original Values of
          Nonpollution Variables
Year
Variable
Number of
observations
COSTS
PSITE
FllAVL
MAINT
TAXES
MVAL6
MVL66
ALMNM
BLK66
BRICK
CRIMX
DLAKE
DILP6
DISSM
DTTYP
FRAME
HSAGE
INCM6
INC66
1NDUT
LTVAR
LOTSZ
MASON
MODUR
NHAGE
NWPP6
OLDER
SQIDX
STORY
TCINC
1964

245
15789
3256
15534
9.63
25.84
16490
18379
.03
37.21
.67
.80
42.52
.09
DO. 15
.90
.22
28.27
7622
8821
5.31
1181
NA
.76
287
44.08
12.39
65.47
2.52
1.36
788


(2896)
(1104)
(2771)
(2.34)
(8.23)
(3309)
(3586)
(.18)
(25.48)
(.471
(.73)
(22.23)
(.22)
(20.92)
(.30)
(.41)
(16.43)
(1153)
(1302)
(6.21)
(293)

(.43)
(52)
(13.57)
(19.32)
(51.79)
(.87)
(.51)
(232)
1965

212
16208
3402
16203
9.46
26.11
16528
18139
.02
28.06
.70
.77
45.86
.09
100.20
.95
.43
30.85
7714
9004
4.72
1213
4620
.56
289
46.34
10.86
71.36
2.27
1.36
806


(3276)
(1237)
(3198)
(2.54)
(8.59)
(2718)
(3905)
(.14)
(21.97)
(.46)
(.54)
(18.67)
(.21)
(19.51)
(.21)
(.50)
(13.75)
(1202)
(1107)
(5.69)
(334)
(3142)
(.50)
(44)
(13.43)
(17.26)
(57.45)
(.73)
(.51)
(222)
1966


16495
3310
16446
9.02
26.42
16174
18056
.06
28.78
.71
.83
44.56
.08
98.78
.95
.29
32.40
7697
8892
4.85
1194
4347
.69
293
47.31
10.35
72.83
2.30
1.41
864

345
(3295)
(1031)
(3203)
(2.31)
(8.32)
(3071)
(3531)
(.23)
(21.65)
(.45)
(.58)
(18.82)
(.21)
(19.70)
(.22)
(.46)
(15.80)
(990)
(1190)
(6.50)
(279)
(2871)
(.46)
(46)
(12.95)
(17.04)
(59.85)
(.74)
(.49)
(271)
1967


17154
3272
17038
10.25
25.71
15695
17274
.15
34.24
.60
.90
47.18
.27
100.94
.95
.39
31.56
7112
8496
5.87
1268
4154
.60
292
49.68
20.05
76.77
2.39
1.40
918

386
(3910)
(946)
(3730)
(3.22)
(7.77)
0020)
(4230)
(.35)
(26.09)
(.49)
,(.62)
(16.22)
!(.48)
(20.04)
(.22)
(.49)
(21.34)
(1372)
(1539)
(6.90)
(312)
(1168)
(.49)
(56)
(12.69)
(26.88)
(59.61)
(.71)
'(.50)
(245)

-------
                                             -74-
Table 4.  Arithmetic Means and Standard Deviations of Original Values of
          Representative Pollution Variables
Year
Variable
PRT64
PRT65
PRT66
SUL64
SUL65
SUL66
PMM64
PMM65
PMM66
SMM64
SMM65
SMM66
PMX64
PMX65
PMX66
SMX64
SMX65
SMV6ft 	
1964
131.43 (11.38)


32.74 (17.54)


90.67 (6.98)


11.01 (4.61)


155.37 (15.73)


64.89 (36.46)

1965
128.05 (10.51)


32.90 (17.47)


91.20 (7.10)


11.17 (4.58)


156.30 (15.40)


64.10 (35.24)

1966
130.22 (10.75)
125.72 (9.59)

33.89 (19.76)
37.38 (15.06)

92.01 (7.11)
98.99 (8.63)

11.14 (4.60)
16.19 (5.60)

158.30 (16.91)
155.20 (8.35)

66.20 (39.85)
63.84 (24.97)
1967
130.09 (10.24)
126.04 (9.94)
138.54 (10.24)
33.43 (20.22)
37.30 (16.82)
50.70 (11.59)
93.38 (8.14)
98.94 (8.0r>
99.09 (15.21)
11.45 (5.44)
15.83 (7.22)
15.80 (3.36)
157.32 (18.15)
157.79 (12.20)
160.32 (14.57)
63.27 (40.28)
63.98 (28.53)

-------
Table 5.  Simple Correlation Coefficients for 1967 Observations.
PSITE
COSTS .578
PSITE
BUC66
DISSM
DLAKE
HSAGE
INC66
iNDirr
LOTSZ
MODUR
TCINC
PRT64
PRT65
PRT66
SUL64
SUL65
SUL66
PVR66
PSK66
SVR66
BLK66 DISSM DLAKE HSAGE INC66
,140 .398 .283 ,561 .357
,130 .328 .080 .234 .111
.010 ,029 .129 ,182
.231 ,515 ,001
.304 .234
.168



'*










JflPJff
.128
.140
.238
.147
*020
.078
.167













LOTSZ
.326
.700
.271
.298
.109
.160
.085
.098












MODUR
.716
.355
.111
.420
.170
.660
.089
.039
.058











TCINC
.513
.297
.122
.014
.059
.234
.221
.128
.256
.240










PRT64
.282
.179
.020
.461
,522
.119
.464
.152
.164
,237
.129









PRT65
.305
.115
.001
.371
.431
.044
.654
.198
,112
.190
.044
.952








PRT66
.314
.128
,003
.296
,284
.038
,636
.091
.114
,190
.163
.960
.967







SUL64
.249
.163
r034
,713
,480
.348
,373
.131
,225
,378
,139
.793
.784
.708






SUL65
.242
-201
.028
.806
.376
.441
.300
.131
.238
,415
,120
.720
.712
.609
.963





SUL66
.369
,262
.163
.792
.530
.511
,126
.112
,226
,426
,142
.604
.542
.457
.811
.913




PVR66
.303




,654


.236
.438
.079


.068


,480



PSK66
.376




.425


,099
,331
,162


.523


.712
,296


SVR66
.329




,430


.099
.383
.070


,435


,968
.348
.663

SSK66
.233




.028


.515
.043
.058


,081


,080
.045
.024
.085

COSTS
PSITE
BLK66
DISSM
DLAKE
HSAGE
INC66
INDUT
LOTSZ
MODUR
TCINC
PRT64
PRT65
PRT66
SUL64
SUL65
SUL66
PVR66
PSK66
SVR66

-------
                                 -76-



      Thc  Inverse  Relation Between Air Pollution Dosages and


 Property  Values.  Table 6 presents the results when, except for


 the  1964  observations, the annual arithmetic mean air pollution


 dosages of  the  immediately preceding year are regressed on the


 FHA-insured  sales taking place during a given year.  Thus, for


 example,  that pollution dosage assumed to influence the offer


 price of  a bundle of housing characteristics purchased at any


 time  in 1966 is the annual arithmetic mean dosage of 1965.  Only


 for 1964  do  the calendar year of the dosages and the transactions


 coincide.  The  figures in parentheses are the associated

                                _2
 coefficients' standard errors.  R   is the portion of unexplained


 variance  adjusted for degrees of freedom, S is the equation's


 standard  error, n is the number of observations, and  ADAM is the


 marginal  capitalized damages to the representative residential


 property due to air pollution dosages.  The latter number is


 evaluated at the arithmetic means of the original values of the


dependent variable and the air pollution variables.  It thus


 represents the marginal capitalized damages for each additional


 annual average of ten micrograms per cubic meter per twenty-four


hours of suspended particulates plus an additional annual average


of one part per billion per twenty-four hours of sulfur dioxide.


     The sum of Table 6's air pollution coefficients has the



-------
-77-
Table 6. I
Year
Variable
Constant
ln(PRT64)
ln(SUL64)
ln(PRT65)
ln(SUL65)
ln(PRT66)
ln(SUL66)
In(TCTNC)
In(LlVAR)
In(HSABE)
In(MODUR)
In(LOTSZ)
In(SQIDX)
In(NHAGE)
In(DISSM)
In (D LAKE)
FRAME
DTTYP
1T2
S
n
DAM
nitial
Regressions. Dependent variable, In
1967
5.3568




T3537
.0296
.3570
.2634
r0438
.3889
.0483
r0648
rll06
.0471
T0236
r0761
.1383
.7711
.1126
388
$428.18
(.9143)




(.1051)
(.0593)
(.0336)
(.0385)
(.0080)
( .0448)
(.0200)
(.0205)
(.0318)
(.0372)
( .0069)
(.0149)
(.0288)




1966
5.0227


T5025
.1298


.3396
.2694
»0490
.3796
.0744
rO 808
»1361
.0453
T0214
*0955
.1228
.6819
.1155
.345
$601.45
(1.1631)


(.1569)
(.1291)


(.0636)
(.0265)
(.0107)
(.0479)
(.0229)
(.0208)
(.0635)
(.0368)
(.0093)
( .0164)
(.0312)




(COSTS)
1965
4.8396
»2207
T1304




.2732
.1873
»0448
.3350
.0489
,1169
T1252
.0543
.0291
T0818
.1347
.7034
.1133
212
$344.12
(1.0461)
(.1616)
(.0270)




(.0366)
(.0388)
(.0157)
(.0627)
(.0258)
(.0317)
(.0574)
(.0420)
(.0234)
(.0188)
(.0405)





1964
5.4809 (
.4343
.0552




.3393
.2726
r0474
.2029

r0609
»1458
»0150
r0186
r0796
.1432
.6022
.1147
244
$510.79
1.1126)
(.1242)
(.0191)




(.0291)
(.0372)
(.0133)
(.0533)

(.0229)
(.0531)
(.0595)
(.0101)
(.0203)
(.0261)




-------
                                -78-
glance at Table 5, the two pollution variables are highly


correlated in each year.  .Application of the Farrar-Glauber [50]


test  to each of the pairs of pollution coefficients in Table 6


always revealed statistically significant multicollinearity.


Further statistical evidence of serious multicollinearity in the


pollution measures is presented in Table 7 below, where each of


the pollution coefficients refers to regressions in which the


other pollution variable was not included.  For example,


ln(TRT66)refers to a regression similar to that for 1967 in Table


6 except that In (SUL66) was dropped.  Similarly In (SUL66) refers


to a  regression in which In (PRT66) is excluded.  As is to be


expected, standard errors, s, of the estimates, b, in Table 7

                                               _2
tend  to decrease relative to those of Table 6, R   decreases


very  little, and the signs of the SUL coefficients change from


positive to negative.


     Table 7.  Initial Regressions with One Pollution Variable.
b
s
K2
1967
ln(PRT66} J.nfSIJL66^
-.5337
.0975
.7683
-.1920
.0472
.7555
1966
-.4163
.1438
.6792
-.2739
.1105
.6781
1965
-.3172
.1249
.7006
lnfsm.641
-.1795
-.0267
.7003
     If one has inspected the simple correlation coefficients

of Table 5, it would appear that the existence of multicollinearity


-------
                                -79-




pollution measures.  In particular, the high simple correlation



coefficients between In(DISSM) , In(DLAKE), and the pollution



measures almost guarantee that dropping the former two variables



from the initial regressions will affect the air pollution



estimates.  Table 8 shows what happens when this is done.  As


expected, the standard errors of the air pollution coefficients



in Table 8 differ from those in Table 6.  However, nowhere is     ,



the change so drastic as to justify acceptance of the null


hypothesis that air pollution has no statistically significant

                                      19
effect on residential property values.    Furthermore, the air



pollution damage elasticities change relatively little so that



the conclusions to be drawn from Table 6 suffer no serious harm.



     It is, of course, possible that the regressions of Table 8



are biased and inconsistent because variables which should be



included, In(DISSM) and In(DLAKE), are not included.  By



partitioning these two variables, it is perhaps possible to avoid



simultaneously the problem of the improper exclusion of a variable


as well as the problem of multicollinearity.  Accordingly, using



1966 sales, Table 9 presents regression coefficients for the air  .



pollution variables where In(DISSM) was partitioned on the basis


of whether or not the residential location was more than ten
                                                                  i

miles from downtown Chicago.  In(DlAKE) was partitioned according




-------
-80-
Table 8.
Year
Variable
Constant
ln(PRT64)
ln(8UL64)
ln(PRT65)
ln(SUL65)
ln(PRT66)
ln(SUL66)
In(TCINC)
In(LIVAR)
In(HSAGE)
In(MODUR)
In(LOTSZ)
In(SOIDX)
In(NHAGE)
FRAME
DTTYP
K2
S
n
DAM
Initial Regressions Without
1967
5.4928




.3625
.0828
.3258
.2492
.0469
.4008
.0544
.0640
.1568
.0878
.1112
.7664
.1140
388
$476.86
(.6914)




(.1057)
(.0441)
(.0254)
(.0386)
(.0061)
(.0439)
(.0239)
(.0220)
(.0457)
(.0148)
(.0299)




In(DISSM)
1966
5.7158


.5587
.1489


.3105
.2259
.0475
.3611
.0664
.0750
.1683
.1004
.1348
.6731
.1171
345
$667.30
(.8441)


(.1674)
(.1106)


(.0570)
(.0240)
(.0109)
(.0486)
(.0232)
(.0205)
(.0802)
(.0165)
(.0320)




and In(DLAKE) .
1965
4.5587
.3560
.0306




.2919
.2318
.0426
.3434
.0598
.0716
.1498
.0850
.1406
.6853
.1161
212
$435.54
(.6042)
(.1097)
(.0192)




(.0302)
(.0334)
(.0072)
(.0540)
(.0220)
(.0267)
(.0619)
(.0190)
(.0 97)




-------
                                           -81-





          Lake  Michigan.  The  specifications of  the  equations  in Table  9



          are  identical  to  those  of Tables, 6, 7, and 8.   If simple



          correlation  coefficients can be  taken  as an indicator of the
                                                                           i


          severity  of  multicol linearity, those of Table 10 would make it



          appear  that  the regression  results of  Table 9 are not severely



          stricken.  This judgment is confirmed  when In(DISSM) and In(DLAKE)





               Table 9.  Regressions  for DISSM and DLAKE Partitions.        '
Partition
Variable
ln(PRT65)
ln(SUL65)
In(DISSM)
In (DLAKE)
2
R
S
n
DISSM
-.2781
.0816
.0892
-.0388

.6807
.1159
185
(
(
(
(




<100
.0874)
.1147)
.0665)
.0194)




DISSM >.
-.5428
.1752
-.0164
-.0422

.6941
.1147
160
(
(
(
(




100
.1974)
.0810)
.0099)
.0266)




DLAKE <30
-.7247
.1594
.0186
-.0583

.6583
.1342
78
(
(
(
(




.1781)
.0297)
.0197)
.0178)




DLAKE
-.4971
.2117
.0716
-.0042

.7110
.1085
267
>. 30
(.1579)
(.0530)
(.0643)
(.0097)




         are dropped  from  the regressions of Table 9.  The exclusion of



         these variables has no meaningful effect upon the standard errors



         of the air pollution coefficients.




         Table  10.   Simple Correlation Coefficients  for  DISSM and D1AKE Partitions




           PISSM < 100"         DISSM -S100          DLAKE < 30          DLAKE 2. 30



        In(DISSM)  In(DLAKE) In (DISSM) In (DLAKE) In (DISSM) In (DLAKE) In (DISSM) In (DLAKE)

In(PRT)   -.2912     -.5136    -.0331    -.6464    -.3026    -.3290    -.4187    -.2556

In(SUL)   -.5481     -.3534    -.4251    -.1313    -.6194    -.0915    -.4813    -.1679





              On  the  basis of the  immediately  preceding  manipulations, we




-------
                                 -82-


 and the air pollution variables  and between In(DLAKE)  and  the  air

 pollution variables does  not  justify  acceptance  of  the null

 hypothesis that air pollution dosages have  no  impact upon  residential

 property values.  However,  simple multicollinearity is not the

 only ground on which the  initial results of Table 6 might  be

 attacked.  For example, In(NHAGE) is  supposed  to be a  composite

 measure registering the effects of neighborhood disaraenities

 other than air pollution  dosages.  Yet  it is quite  possible that

 this variable  does  not register those disamenities  which are

 correlated with air pollution dosages.  If,  for example, air

 pollution dosages  tend to be  higher where a  substantial proportion

 of  the  sirrounding  land area  is devoted to  industrial  uses and if
         4
 these uses generate residential disamenities unrelated  to air

 pollution,  then the air pollution results of Table  6 may reflect

 the  presence of these  disamenities.   Similarly, if  air pollution

dosages  tend to be  heaviest in areas  populated by blacks or by low

 income  people,  and  if  others  attach greater disutility to being

near  these  groups than the utility the group members obtain being

close to  each  other, then the air pollution variables would

register  the net negative effects upon the polluted area.

      In Table  11, tests of these hypothesis are made by partitioning

the  sample.  The first regression employs all 1966 property sales


-------
                                -83-
flve porcenl of its area devoted to industrial uses.  The last




three regressions employ 1966 and 1967 transactions.  Except




perhaps for the regression for 1966 and 1967 transactions in which




BLK66   75, the air pollution coefficients of Table 11 are not at





     Table 11.  Regressions for INDUT, BLK66, and INC66 Partitions
Partition
Variable
Constant
ln(PRT65)
ln(SUL65)
In(TCINC)
In(LIVAR)
In(HSAGE)
In(MODUR)
In(LOTSZ)
In(SQIDX)
In(NHAGE)
In(DISSM)
In(DLAKE)
FRAME
DTTYP
In(CRlMX)
R
s
n
INDUT
6.9438
-.5174
.1297
.3113
.2177
-.0475
.3673
.0446
-.0792
-.0227
.0689
-.0387
-.1039
.1308

.6265
.1190
227
< 5
(.9718)
(.1810)
(.0385)
( .0344)
(.0455)
(.0155)
(.0651)
(.0288)
(.0243)
(.0295)
(.0571)
(.0199)
(.0218)
(.0386)




BLK66
8.0918
-.7331
.2077
.2835
.2015
-.0521
.3783
.0167
-.0291

.0446
-.0346
-.0736
.1578
-.0456
.7186
.1199
254
< 25
(.9804)
(.1633)
(.0457)
(.0302)
(.0399)
(.0092)
(.0517)
(.0268)
(.0288)

(.0577)
(.0196)
(.0178)
(.0299)
(.0177)



BLK66
6.7449
-.5388
.2434
.1600
.1066
-.0283
.5955
.0301
.0162

.1151
-.1582
-.0440
.0713
-.1954
.7005
.1288
76
>. 75
(2.2473)
( .6278)
( .3618)
( .0724)
( .0799)
( .0227)
( .1371)
( .0899)
( .0899)

( .2105)
( .0984)
( .0492)
( .1054)
( .1770)



BLK66
and
INC66 1
9.5894 (1
-.8263 (
.2781 (
.3537 (
.2401 (
-.0561 (
.3388 (
-.0091 (
-.0063 (

.0520 (
-.0462! (
-.0793 (
.1378 (
-.0459 (
.7082
.1159
194
25
8495
.2727)
.2167)
.0704)
.0357)
.0483)
.0116)
.0632)
.0288)
.0406)

.0501)
.0269)
.0218)
.0320)
.0225)



 all  inconsistent with those of previous tables.  The results for




 BLK  ,1 75 can easily be due to the relatively small degrees of




 freedom and the fact that within this partition the standard




 deviation of ln(PRT65) was only one percent of its mean while the




 standard deviation ln(SUL65) was only six percent of its mean.





-------
                                 -84-
 l'ropi!rL>  Data.   MulCicollinearity  and  the  improper  exclusion of

 variables have  not  greatly bothered  previous  studies  of  this sort.

 Instead,  as was earlier  noted,  concern has been  exhibited  about

 measurement error caused by discrepancy between  the years  of

 observed  property transactions  and observed air  pollution  dosages.

 Table  12  below  compares  the results  for 1967  property transactions

 when the  years  to which  the air pollution  dosages differ.  The

 individual regresssions  therefore  differ only in the  year  to

 which  the air pollution  dosages refer.  The specifications of

 Table  12  as did  three  of the four regressions of Table  11 differ

 slightly  from those of Table 6  in  that In(CRIMX) was  included as

 an explanatory  variable  while In(NHAGE) was excluded.  These two

 variables, having a simple correlation coefficient  of .68  for 1967

 transactions, are collinear.  The  inclusion of both in the same

 equation  has a  substantial impact  upon their  standard  errors.



 Table  12.  Regressions Exhibiting  Discrepencies  in  Air Pollution and
 I'rrjner tV  S ll f T)af"J*
onstant
In(PRT)
In(SUL)
IT
S
ADAM
!"• ' ' * 	 linn.
1966
4.1532 (1.0984)
-.3998 ( .1509)
.0601 ( .0501)
.7763
.1116
$474.96
1965
4.1426 (1.1272)
-.4258 ( .1223)
.1223 ( .0345)
.7815
.1103
$601.45
1964
4.1837 (.9626)
-.4557 (.1407)
.0808 (.0226)
.7836
.1098
$541.93
     Employing a method proposed by Tiao and Goldberger [56] , an


-------
                                -85-
oqualIty among years in the air pollution coefficients of Table 12.


Table 13 presents the results of this test, where the columns


refer to the combination of years for the air pollution dosages,


F is the value of the F-test, and  Z(T-K) is the sum of the


transactions employed in the regressions less the number of


variables.  Only for ln(PRT64) and ln(PRT65) can the null hypothesis


be accepted.  However, on strictly intuitive grounds, it is


difficult to discern any very important differences in any of the


sums of the two pollution coefficients.  An awareness of our inability


to describe with exactitude the synergic properties of the two


pollutants can neither deny nor fail to deny one's intuitions about


these results.  Nevertheless, such an awareness does raise doubts


about the validity of using a statistical procedure which presupposes


that the coefficients being compared are measured in identical


units.  A similar caveat applies to all analyses of covariance set

                    20
forth in this study.



Table 13.  Analysis of Covariance of 1967 Disaggregated FHA Data

(T-K)
F
I
ln(PRT65,66)
742
13.08

ln(PRT64,65)
742
.78

ln(PRT64,65,66)
1113
12.80

ln(SUL65,66)
742
43.17

ln(SUL64,65)
742
33.70

ln(SUL64,65,66)
1113
26.21

    >/Aggregation Bias.  A  test  similar  to  that above  can be



-------
                                -86-





acquired as  to whether or not census results tend to exhibit



aggregation bias.  Table 14 presents regression results using



census data.  The air pollution dosages for each census tract



correspond to the dosages found at an individual FHA-insured



residential property near the center of the,tract.  Each column



indicates the year to which the air pollution dosages refer.



     An analysis of covariance of the air pollution coefficients



of Table 14 yielded not a pair fulfilling the null hypothesis of



equality of the coefficients for different mean annual pollution



dosages.  Again, however, the differences do not appear



particularly important to the eye, if one again bases his judgment



upon the sum of the coefficients.



     More interesting perhaps is a comparison of the air pollution



coefficients obtained using the census data of Table 14 to the air



pollution coefficients obtained using the disaggregated FHA data



of Table 12.  If the air pollution coefficients obtained using



each of the two data sets are statistically equivalent, then the



null hypothesis of an aggregation bias being present in the air



pollution estimates obtained employing census data cannot be


         21
accepted.    The results of an analysis of covariance to test



this hypothesis are presented in Table 15.  The columns refer to



the variables common to both the FHA and the census regressions




-------
                                            -87-



Table 14.  Regression Results for Census Data.   Dependent variable,  ln(MVAL6).

Constant
In(PRT)
In(SUL)
ln(INCM6)
ln(DILP6)
In (OLDER)
ln(NWPP6)
In(DISSM)
In(DLAKE)
In(SQIDX)
E
S
n
ADAM
1966
4.9049
-.5515
.1839
.6182
.0068
-.0269
.0103
.1458
-.0425
-.0769
.5763
.1391
156
$418.73
(1.5794)
( .2307)
( .1066)
( .1180)
( .0050)
( .0133)
( .0054)
( .0670)
( .0298)
( .0400)




1965
5.1712
-.5740
.2410
.6036
.0069
.0220
.0112
.1294
-.0067
-.0820
.5820
.1352
156
$604.64
(1.3420)
( .1841)
( .0560)
( .0980)
( .0049)
( .0119)
( .0041)
( .0583)
( .o:>74)
( .0408)




1964 |
4.6524
-.3754
.0654
.6124
.0039
-.0240
.0127
.1390
.0089
-.0751
.5902
.1339
156
$426.19
(1.2799)
( .1485)
( .0336)
( .1176)
( .0049)
( .0125)
( .0042)
( .0588)
( .0301)
( .0301)




Table 15.  Analysis of Covariance of Disaggregated FHA and Census Data.

(T-K)
F
ln(PRT66)
514
1.39
ln(PRT65)
514
8.69
ln(PRT64)
514
1.97
ln(SUL66)
514
6.60
ln(SUL65)
514
16.60
ln(SUL64)
514
2.17
                 In Table 15, ln(PRT66), ln(PRT64), and ln(SUL64)  have values




            of F suitable for failing to reject the hypothesis of equality




            of the coefficients for these variables in the two data sets.  The




            values of F for ln(PRT65), ln(SUL66),  and ln(SUL65) do not fulfill




            the customary statistical criterion.   Nevertheless, though the




            results of Table 15 do not entirely justify it, the writer is




            inclined to dismiss the practical importance of any aggregation





-------
                                -88-






If any aggregation bias is in fact present in the census data, on




the basis of these results one must attach a rather high value to




the complete absence of bias in order to justify the effort




required to compile and analyze disaggregated FHA or similar data.




     The available data permitted a higher level of aggregation




to community areas, a collection of several census tracts.




Observations on forty-six community areas were used in regressions




where MVL66 was the dependent variable and the natural logarithms




of PRT65, SUL65, INC66, SQIDX, DISSM, DLAKE, and BLK66 were the




explanatory variables.  The sum of the air pollution coefficients




was -.2527 and marginal capitalized damages were $438.54.  However,




the natural logs of the air pollution variables and In(DISSM)  were




collinear.  When the forty-six observations were partitioned by




DISSM, both air pollution coefficients became statistically




insignificant, though their sum continued to be negative.  The




question of whether or not meaningful air pollution damages




estimates can be obtained when the unit of observation is larger



than a census tract therefore remains open.



     The Use of Assessed Property Values.  Census data and



disaggregated FHA data are not the only data sources from which




air pollution damages to residential properties could conceivably




be estimated.  For example a wide variety of local and state





-------
                                -89-
                                                        0

structural characteristics.  In its first three columns, Table 16

prescntt1.  results  for 1967 FHA-insured property sales when In(FHAVL)

and  In(TAXES) serve as dependent variables.  An analysis of

covariance of the air pollution coefficients in the first column

of Table  16 and the 1967 column of Table 6 reveals no statistically

significant difference in the coefficients for ln(PRT66), though

the  coefficients  for ln(SUL66) do exhibit such a difference.

In(FHAVL) would thus appear to be fairly satisfactory proxy for

In(COSTS).                                                       !
                                                                 *
     Of the explanatory variables employed in the first column of;

Table 16, only In(TCINC) or a similar measure of individual

household income  is unlikely to be obtainable from publicly

accessible records.  Though it has been shown in Anderson and

Crocker [l],  that a failure to include an income variable        :

in an offer price equation results in a misspecification and its

attendant biases  and inconsistencies, it is of interest to obtain

an empirical indication of the direction and magnitude of this

bias.  The second column of Table 16 therefore duplicates the

specification of  the first column except that no income variable

has been  included.  Though increases in the pollution variables
           0
and decreases in  the income variable tend to have a depressing

effect upon offer price, they are inversely correlated in the


-------
                                          -90-
Table 16.  Regressions with In(FHAVL).  In(TAXES).  and In(MAINT)  as Dependent
       Dependent
Independent In(FHAVL)
Constant
ln(PRT66)
ln(SUL66)
In(TCINC)
In(LIVAR)
In(HSAGE)
In(MODUR)
In(LOTSZ)
In(SOIDX)
In(NHAGE)
In(DISSM)
In(DLAKE)
FRAME
DTTYP
MASON
BRICK
ALMNM
STORY
£
S
n
ADAM
4.7574
-.3218
-.0088
.3420
.2115
-.0371
.4047
.0924
-.0659
-.0942
.0285
-.0219
-.0800
.0997




.8007
.1001
386
$399.12
(.6285)
(.0927)
(.0472)
(.0219)
(.0250)
(.0052)
(.0392)
(.0217)
(.0176)
(.0351)
(.0111)
(.0121)
(.0131)
(.0268)








In(FHAVL)
5.5620
-.4185
-.0090

.2094
-.0407
.4382
.0904
-.0856
-.1213
.0574
-.0539
-.1201
.1496




.7244
.1121
386
$505 . 75
(.5133)
(.1192)
(.0506)

(.0313)
(.0058)
(.0411)
(.0234)
(.0175)
(.0709)
(.0502)
(.0152)
(.0178)
(.0330)








In (TAXES)
-1.2340
-.2638
.1069
.3515
.2011
-.0299
.0784
.1164
-.0564

.0256
-.0263
-.0901
.0418




.6611
.1051
386
$ .44
(.6601)
(.0974)
(.0496)
(.0230)
(.0263)
(.0055)
(.0412)
(.0228)
(.0184)

(.0133)
(.0142)
(.0137)
(.0282)








In(MAINT)
1.8061
-.3081
-.0179

.3910
-.0305






-.0818

-.0438
.0620
.0455
-.0461
.5719
.0975
386
	
(.5247)
(.1101)
(.0221)

(.0246)
(.0046)






(.0459)

(.0472)
(.0219)
(.0203)
(.0115)




          the negative magnitude of  the pollution coefficients.   As  is

          evident in the second  column of Table 16,  the bias  that is

          introduced appears to  be rather substantial.

               The third column  of Table 16 employs  monthly payments of

          locally assessed property taxes as the dependent variable.  Since

          the coefficients are elasticity measures,  one would expect them

          to be identical to those found in the 1967 column of Table 6 if

          property taxes constitute the same proportion of the sale  price


-------
                                 -91-






 eye  says  the  coefficients differ.  What  the; naked eye says is




 confirmed by  an  analysis of covariance.  It would seem that the




 City  of Chicago's  residential property assessors understate the




 effects of air pollution.




      Maintenance Expenditures.   In the fourth column of Table 16




 is presented  the results for a regression in which In(MAINT) is




 employed as the  dependent variable.  These results are totally




 contrary  to expectations since the air pollution coefficients have




 negative rather  than positive signs attached to them.  If one




 considers only the maintenance the FHA's "average resident" would




 undertake, it seems unlikely that increased air pollution results




 in reduced maintenance outlays upon a given bundle of housing




 characteristics.  Nevertheless,  reduced expenditures on maintenance




with  increasing  air pollution dosages are not inconsistent with




 our earlier hypothesis that householders In locations experiencing




 relatively heavy dosages have revealed a lesser willingness to




 pay for a clean  environment.




      Effects of Dosages Upon Site Values.  One of the major




hypotheses presented in the section dealing with the theoretical




 framework for this study was the greater sensitivity of site




values than property values to variations in air pollution




dosages.  A test of this hypothesis is available in Table 17,





-------
                                     -92-






      transactions  took place.  In each year, the sum of  the air




      pollution coefficients has the expected negative sign, and



      In(PRT)  is always statistically significant at the  generally




      accepted levels.  When one or the other of the air  pollution




      variables is dropped from the regression, the remaining variable




      always assumes a negative sign and is always statistically




Table 17.  Regressions for Site Values.  Dependent Variable, In(PSITE).
1967
Constant
ln(PRT64)
ln(SUL64)
ln(PRT65)
ln(SUL65)
ln(PRT66)
ln(SUL66)
In(TCINC)
In(LOTSZ)
In(SOIDX)
ln(INC66)
In(DISSM)
In(DLAKE)
In(CRIMX)
In(NHAGE)
^
S
n
DAM
9.8624




-.7915
.0183
.2719
.3633
-.1265
.2650
.1937
-.0847
- . 1088
-.0510
.6194
.1751
386
$191.09
(1.8545)




( .2691)
( .0920)
( .0380)
( .0329)
( .0392)
( .0883)
( .1142)
( .0270)
( .0328)
( .0457)




1966
7.0144


-1.7651
.4516


.2231
.3750
-.0514
.2730
.2156
-.1102
-.0312
-.0343
.4983
.1954
345
$323.85
(2.0440)


( .3112)
( .0786)


( .0387)
( .0367)
( .0385)
( .1176)
( .1004)
( .0268)
( .0233)
( .0345)




1965
-2.1833
-.7128
.1507




.2581
.2565
-.2101
.4391
.1879
-.0529
-.0012
-.0043
.5138
.2264
188
$167.00
(2.9518)
( .2896)
( .0551)




( .0416)
( .0496)
( .0607)
( .1367)
( .0984)
( .0470)
( .0332)
( .0603)




     significant at the .05 level of the one-tailed t-test.  As was




     the case in the initial regressions of Table 6, In(DISSM) and




     In(DLAKE)  tended to be somewhat correlated with the air pollution




     variables.  The exclusion of In(DISSM) and In(DLAKE) had no





-------
                                -93-






variables however; nor did the dropping of In(PRT) and In(SUL)




have any appreciable effect upon the standard errors of the two




distance variables.




     The important feature of Table 17*s air pollution coefficients




emerges when the marginal capitalized damages falling from them  ,




are compared to the marginal capitalized damages falling from the




air pollution coefficients of Table 6.  In each of the three



years for which regressions were run, the ratio of average




marginal site damages to average site value was greater than the




ratio of average marginal property damages to average property




value.  Similarly, the sum of the air pollution elasticities in




the site value regressions is always greater than the sum of the




same coefficients in the property value regressions.  This



outcome is consistent with our hypothesis that land or site




values are more sensitive to air pollution dosages than are




property values.



     Declining Marginal Damages.  Results consistent with another.




earlier stated hypothesis are set forth in Table 18 where the    :




1966 property sale observations are partitioned by three distinct




intervals of sulfur dioxide dosages.  Thus, the observations



included in the regression for the column headed SUL65 ^25 include



all those 1966 property sales from the disaggregated FHA data





-------
                                -94-
per billion or less of sulfur dioxide.  The other two columns




have analogous meanings.

ln(PRT65)
ln(SUL65)
ADAM
n
SUL65
-.6938
.2001
$802.83
74
<25
(.2219)
(.0610)


, 25 < SUL65 <-45
-.4938
.1135
$574.56
149
( . 1874)
(.1372)


SUL65
-.3892
.1521
$427.31
122
>45
(.1062)
(..0610)


     Without bothering to resort to statistical tests to ascertain




whether the observations for the three regressions of Table 18




were drawn from the same population, the above results appear to




be consistent with our hypothesis of declining aggregate marginal




damages.  This assertion is statistically confirmed by the failure




of an analysis of covariance to find a significant difference in




the populations of the first and second columns.  However, the




covariance analysis rejected the hypothesis that the observations




of the third column came from the same statistical population as




the observations of the first two columns.  Thus one cannot




claim that all three sets of pollution coefficients correspond to




different points on the same damage function.  Nevertheless, the




fact that this claim can be made for two sets of the coefficients




provides some evidence that the aggregate marginal damage function




declines at least over low and intermediate ranges of air pollution




dosages.




     Some further more or less impressionistic support for the




hypothesis of a declining aggregate marginal damage function is





-------
Table 19.  Comparison of Logarithmic Means and Pollution Coefficients
Dependent
.Variable
In (COSTS)
In(COSTS)
In (COSTS)
In (COSTS)
In (COSTS)
In(PSITE)
In(PSITE)
In(PSITE)
In (COSTS)
In (COSTS)
In (COSTS)
In (COSTS)
In (COSTS)
In (COSTS)
In(COSTS)
In (COSTS)
In(COSTS)
In(COSTS)
In(COSTS)
T YEAR
67
67
66,67
66,67
66.67
66,67
66,67
66.67
66
66
66
66
65,66,67
65,66,67
65,66,67

65,66,67
65,66^67
65
65
Partition
MODUR > 300
200 < MODUR <300
BLK66 >75
BLK66 <25
BLK < .25 and
INC66 >8495
BLK66 > 75
BLK66 £25
BLK <25 and
INC66 >8495
DISSM 1100
DISSM >100
DLAKE >30
DLAKE <30
HSAGE > 40
20 1 HSAGE £40
HSAGE < 20

None
TCINC > 850
None
INDUT <5

In(PRT)
4.9206
4.8746
4.9160
4.8322
4.8163
4.9160
4.8322
4.8163

4.8638
4.7936
4.8593
4.7810
4.8640
4.8681
4.8455

4.8593
4.8639
4.8553
4.8464

In(SUL)
3.8521
3.5282
3.7983
3.5091
3.4053
3.7983
3.5091
3.4053

3.8110
3.2438
3.5174
3.2516
3 .4438
3.4107
3.0848

3.3343
3.3049
3.3467
3.3010
bPRT
-.2376*
-.6913
-.5388*
-.7331
-.8263
U2390*
-2.1870
-2.4939

-.2781
-.5428
-.4971
-.7247
-.3795
-.2447
-.7665

-.3560
-.4475
-.2207*
-.5174
bSLJL
.0172V
.0866-v
.2434*
.2077
.2781
-.0914*
.3670
.5108

.0816*'
.1752
.2117
.1594
.0217*
-.1506
.1075*

.0227
.0374
-.1304
.1297
                                                                                                                I
                                                                                                               \0
                                                                                                               Ui

-------
                                -96-


partitions of  the data set can be compared.  The regression is listed
                                        i
in  the dependent variable column.  Reading across the rows, the columns

refer respectively to the year in which fhe property sales occurred,

the nature of  the partition, the arithmetic mean of the natural logarithm

of average annual monthly suspended particulates in the year preceding

the earliest year of the regression's property sale observations, the

arithmetic mean of the natural logarithm of average annual monthly

sulfur dioxide in the year preceding the earliest year of the regression's

property sale observations, the regression coefficient for In(PRT),

and, finally,  the regression coefficient for In(SUL).  The horizontal

double lines are intended to separate partitions of different variables,

while the starred regression coefficients indicate nonsignificance

at the .05 level of the one-tailed t-test.

     Since arithmetic means were not calculated for the original values

of the variables in each of Table 19's partitions, the presentation

can neither confirm nor deny the hypothesis of a declining aggregate

marginal damage function.  In addition, since no analyses of covariance

were performed upon the coefficients of the regressions for the partitions,

one cannot know whether observations were drawn from the same statistical

population.  Nevertheless, a cursory view of Table 19 makes it appear

that damage elasticities tend to decline with increasing air pollution

dosages.  If the ratio of property value to air pollution dosages remains

fairly constant throughout, a declining damage elasticity is consistent

with a declining marginal damage function.  The earlier results of


-------
                                -97-


 the aggregate marginal damages of Table 19 would also tend to
                                                   a
decline.

     The Minimax Decision Criterion.  If it is in fact the case

 that marginal damages are greater at low than at  high levels

of pollution dosages, one would expect differential property

values' to be more sensitive to differences in minimum dosages

 than to differences in maximum dosages.  Table 20 shows six

regressions for 1966 and 1967 property sale observations, where,

except for the air pollution variables, the specifications were

identical to the initial regressions of Table 6.  The results

presented in Table 20 are again fully consistent with the

hypothesis of a declining aggregate marginal damage function.

It should be recognized, however, that PMM and PMX are highly

correlated with each other anc with PRT, while SMX and SUL are

also highly correlated.  The regressions of Table 20 in which

both minimum and maximum pollution dosages are included as

regressors obviously exhibit this collinearity.  Its presence

inhibits any meaningful test of the hypothesis of the receptor's

use of a rainimax decision criterion in response to uncertainty

about future pollution dosages.

     The Cubic Utility Function.  In another of the hypotheses

developed in a previous section about receptor responses to


-------
                                   -98-
Table 20.  Regressions for Minimum and Maximum Air Pollution Dosages

ln(PMM66)
ln(SMM66)
ln(PMX66)
ln(SMX66)
£*
S
n
ADAM
1967
-.2267 (.0527)
-.1194 (.0350)


.7722
.1123
388
$522.40
1967


-.2071 (.0719)
-.0209 (.0349)
.7641
.1143
388
$224.89
1967
-.3139
-.1283
.0383
.0607
.7721
.1124
388


(.0936)
(.0397)
(.0954)
(.0457)





ln(PMM65)
ln(SMM65)
ln(PMX65)
ln(SMX65)
£
S
n
ADAM
1966
-.4333 (.0919)
-.0557 (.0258)


.6916
.1141
345
$778.78
1966


-.4629 (.1301)
.0643 (.0223)
.6669
.1182
345
$474.72
1966
-.3758
-.0370
-.3642
.1132
.6915
.1143
345


(.1101)
(.0399)
(.1436)
(.0375)




   utility function in air pollution, then the second and third




   moments of the annual distribution of pollution dosages become




   relevant to damages.  Table 21 presents regression results for




   1965, 1966, and 1967 property sale observations when various




   combinations of the first, second, and third moments of the




   distribution of air pollution dosages are included as regressors.




   Again, except for the air pollution variables,  the specifications




   were identical to the initial regressions of Table 6.  All air




   pollution measures in Table 21 refer to the dosages occurring in





-------
                                     -99-






     1 is tied in the columns.




Table 21.  Regressions on Second and Third Moments of Pollution Dosages

In(PRT)
In(SUL)
In (PVR)

In(SVR)

In(PSK)

In(SSK)
2
I
S
n
1967
-.4453 1
-.1784 <
-.0195 I
-4
- . 14x10 1
-4
- . 73x10 1
.3
-.25x10 <

.7761
.1121
388

M133)
M525)
(.0248)
_4
;. 16x10 )
-4
(.36x10 )
-3
(. 12x10 )




1967
-.4570 1
-.0407 (



-4
.68x10 <
-3
-.24x10 I

.7756
.1122
388

(.1084)
(.0459)



-4
(.36x10 )
-3
(.12x10 )




1966
-.5793
.1835
-.0112
-5
.13x10
-5
-.64x10
-4
.74x10

.6831
.1149
345

(.1700)',
(.0515)
( .0304)
-5
(.49x10 )
-4
(.19x10 )
-4
(.85x19 )



i


In(PRT)
In(SUL)
In (PVR)
In(SVR)

In(PSK)
In(SSK)
_2
R
S
n
1966
-.6495 (
.1290 <


-5
-.87x10 <
.68xlO"4 (

.6827
.1150
345

M491)
(.0295)


-4
M9xio )
;.79xlo"4)




1965
-.3163 (
-.1521 1
-.0265 (
-. 14x10 "4 |
-4
-.72x10 <
-.31x10" <

.7258
.1124
212

(.1693)
(.0351)
(.0294)
(.21xlO~4)
-4
(.31x10 )
-3
(.14x10 )




1965
-.3206
-.0692


-4
-.75x10
-3
-.31x10

.7188
.1125
212

(.1517)'
(.0276);


-4
(.32x10 )
-3
( . 13x10 )




          The results presented in Table 21 are rather ambiguous.




     Nowhere does the inclusion of the second moment divided by the




     mean yield a statistically significant coefficient, though the





-------
     :                          -100-




fnr  "he measure of air pollution variance does not appedr to


be due entirely to multicollinearity problems for only ln(SVR66)


and  ln(SUL66) have an extremely high simple correlation coefficient.


The drastic changes which always occur in the standard errors of


In(SUL) whenever In(SVR) is added or dropped are strong evidence

                             22
of multicollinearity however.


     The results for the skewness measures in Table 21 are


somewhat more meaningful.  In two of the three years, 1967 and


1965, each of the skewness variables is statistically significant.


In ttvj third year, 1966, where the skewness variables are not


significant, the arithmetic means and standard deviations of the


natural logarithms of the variables were no more than one-half


the values of the other two years.  In fact, the mean of ln(SSK66)


was so small as to be practically nonexistent.  Further support


for the meaningfulness of the skewness variables is offered by


the fact that their signs, except for ln(PSK66), are in accord


with expectations.  For example, the sign of the arithmetic


mean of ln(SSK66)  is positive, implying that the air pollution


distribution of 1966 for the locations of the 1967 property sale


observations was skewed toward the higher pollution dosages.


Given that disutility is attached to a greater density of pollution


at the higher dosages, the sign of the coefficient for ln(SSK66)



-------
                               -101-


ln(PSK66) is negative, implying a greater density for suspended

particulates in 1966 at the lower dosages.  As expected, the sign

of  ln(PSK66)'s coefficient is positive.

     Adaptive Expectations.  The results presented in Table 21

constitute the last of this study's economic-theoretic and

statistical hypotheses which were tested by suitable estimation
                                                               i
procedures.  The one hypothesis, the adaptive expectations

hypothesis, for which no meaningful results have been or will be
                                                               i
presented, was originally viewed as one of the study's major   .

objectives.

     The intent of the study was to test the adaptive expectations

hypothesis by means of a nonlinear distributed lag regression

program capable of carrying out estimation where at least two

variables in a cross-sectional expression were vector-valued
                                23
while others were scalar-valued.    In conjunction with those

transactions taking place in 1967, two different forms of the

air pollution data were used.  First, monthly observations of

the mean daily dosages of each pollutant starting at the month of

sale and in some regression runs extending as far back as January,

1964, were employed.  Second, only the mean annual concentrations

for 1966, 1965, and 1964 were used.  Whatever the air pollution

data, moderately different results were obtained according to   ;


-------
                               -102-

                                                                f\t
 the  complete  lag expression and  the lag  term of  this expression.

 Never were  statistically meaningful results obtained when  the

 monthly air pollution data were  introduced.  However, results

 having moderate degrees of statistical significance were

 occasionally  encountered when the annual air pollution data were

 entered.

     In terms of statistical significance and intuitive

 reasonableness, the "best" results with  these annual air pollution

 data are presented in Table 22.  Except  for the  lag expressions

 introduced  for the pollution variables,  the specification was the

 same as in  the initial regressions of Table 6.  Separate lag

 expressions were specified for suspended particulates and sulfur

 dioxide.  The coefficients for all other explanatory variables

 closely approximated those of Table 6.  The percentage of variation

 explained in  the dependent variable was also similar.

Table 22.  Example of Distributed Lag Results.	

               PRT                      SUL

b      -.0019       (.0010)       .0005      (.0004)
A	.5094	(.0024)	.2966	(.8378)

     At no time did APRT or ASUL approach unity.  Thus one can

be fairly safe in asserting that some lag effect does appear to

exist in the formation of expectations about future air pollution

dosages.  If one insists upon accepting the results in Table 22


-------
                                -103-






between fifty and eighty percent of the expectations held about




air pollution dosages in any following twelve months are accounted




for by the air pollution dosages of the previous twelve months.




The fifty percent figure applies when one dismisses the




statistically insignificant for sulfur dioxide.  It should again




be strongly emphasized, however, that results having a degree of




statistical resolution even approximately like those of Table 22!




were obtained in only a minority of cases.  In short, though its




other results can be viewed as useful, this study contributes no!




trustworthy empirical insights into the relation between residential




property values and histories of air pollution dosages.






Some Desirable Research Extensions




     Whenever one constructs a formal model of a real situation,




one is attempting to express in an internally consistent manner




a conviction as to which of the situation's elements are trivial




and which are essential.  A bounded rationality requires that one




pick and choose.  It is a commonplace of statistical inference




that these convictions can be rejected but never completely




accepted by comparing their implications with observations on




real situations.  The best one can do is fail to reject the




convictions.  It is worth noting, however, that even a rejection




must rest upon some self-convincing interpretation of one's





-------
                                -104-






     In order to secure reality somewhat more closely, this




paper's primary focus has been upon an expansion of the elements




to be regarded as nontrivial in air pollution damage contexts.




Inevitably, this means a more detailed economic-theoretic




framework and the development of a greater number of testable




hypotheses, the empirical implications for each of which are more



visible for critical scrutiny by those whose notions of the




trivial and the nontrivial vary.  However, if the number of




elements to be regarded as essential is continually expanded,




some agreement on criteria for rejection must ultimately occur.




Given the results of this paper and its author's implied convictions,




this section attempts to suggest some elements of air pollution




damage contexts which might now be regarded as essential.  The



section deals in turn with theoretical, estimation, and empirical




elements of air pollution damage investigations.



     Theoretical Issues.  During his reading of the theoretical




framework of this paper, the perceptive reader will have noted




that the movement from the derivation of the offer function for




bundles of housing characteristics to the derivation of the form




of the marginal damage function was made via a one sentence




application of the composite goods theorem.  In short, once the




offer function had been dealt with, it was assumed thereafter that




-------
                                -105-






in a bundle of housing characteristics were invariant.  This not




innocuous step permitted the variables in all later theoretical




developments  to be treated as if they were scalar rather than




vector-valued.  A subsequent investigation should attempt to




ascertain whether such conclusions as the declining marginal




damage  function and the greater sensitivity of land than improvement




values  to air pollution dosages can be maintained under the same




derivation of the offer function but without resorting to the




composite goods theorem.




     With the one minor exception of the minimax decision criterion




where constant marginal costs of supplying bundles of housing




characteristics had to be assumed, any consideration of the supply




function for these bundles was avoided by assuming the stock of the




bundles to be always in a long-run equilibrium.  There exist four




ways of adjusting the stock of housing characteristics:  (1)  a




positive replacement demand—as characteristics depreciate they are




replaced;  (2)  a negative replacement demand—as characteristics




depreciate they are not replaced;  (3)   a combinational process




whereby new characteristics are joined with characteristics that




are already joined together—a new activity in the terminology




adopted by Lancaster  14  ; and (4) the construction of entirely




new bundles of housing characteristics.  The stock of housing





-------
                                -106-
                                                           f

these  four ways is operative.  A glance out one's window is a

convincing argument for the pervasiveness of the latter three ways

and  thus  the extent of disequilibrium in the stock of housing

characteristics.  Therefore a model which intends to include all

general classes of factors influencing the inventory of housing

characteristics must have some means of explaining discrepancies

between actual and desired inventories and the manner in which

suppliers of housing characteristics respond to these discrepancies<

Such a model would be aware that changes In expected air pollution

dosages can be a cause of any discrepancy between actual and

desired inventories of housing characteristics.

     A recognition that a long-run equilibrium may not persist in

markets for bundles of housing characteristics implies that the

production of these bundles is responsive to changes in air

pollution dosages.  That is, in addition to the price adjustments

to changing air pollution dosages which have been explicitly

recognized throughout this study, a quantity adjustment can occur

as well.  When a quantity adjustment can enter, the possibility

that the damage function relevant to increasing air pollution

dosages differs from the damage function relevant to decreasing

air pollution dosages emerges.  This possibility could be of real

importance in situations where the values of fixed assets such as

bundles of housing characteristics are afflicted by air pollution


-------
                                -107-




     Remembering that we view the householder as purchasing housing



goods  to generate bundles of housing characteristics, consider the



problem the householder faces in his decision to increase, maintain,

                                                                 I

or divest himself of a given b.undle.  Anyone who has ever



participated in the housing market is aware that there are       •



substantial expenses (closing costs, real estate agent's fees,


prepayment penalties, etc.) associated with the acts of purchasing



or selling a house.  In general, at any point in time for the



individual householder these expenses cause acquisition price,



p., to be at least as great as sale price, p .  Otherwise, one
 A                                          s


could always make money by reselling immediately.  Thus in long-run



equilibrium it must be that p.    dz  p   p , where p is the
                             A    '-'  '      S
                                  dx

willingness of the householder to pay for an additional unit of the



housing characteristics bundle.  A simple arithmetic example



lends insight to the difficulties this formulation can introduce.


     Let us assume that the acquisition costs on a $20,000 house



are $500 and the selling costs are $1,000.  Thus, assuming that  .


air pollution is the sole cause of variations in p, under no     !



circumstances would the householder sell the house unless his air .



pollution damages were at least $1,000.  Now let us assume that


for some reason air pollution decreases and the householder must



decide whether or not to acquire the same bundle of housing




-------
                                -108-






damages  caused by  the decrease in air pollution was at least $500.



 In  short,  the mix  and magnitude of bundles the householder holds




over  a given interval of air pollution dosages can differ according




 to  whether air pollution dosages are increasing or decreasing.  At




 identical  levels of air pollution dosages, the same individual




householder can be employing different mixes and magnitudes of
                                                              i


housing  goods and  can therefore suffer different air pollution




damages.   It may therefore be worthwhile in future investigations



to  investigate in  depth the theoretical and the empirical




implications of this point.  Intuitively, the point would seem to




imply that the construction of some empirically usable measure of




the trend  of the air pollution dosage history would be advisable.




     Another of the issues carefully avoided in this study's



theoretical framework was that of the determinants of the




householder's sensitivity to air pollution dosages.  Thus the



assertion was made that sensitivities do in fact differ among



householders and the analysis was carried through to its conclusions



on  the basis of this assertion.  No attention whatsoever was



devoted  to the not unimportant question of why these sensitivities



differ.  The lack  of attention given to these determinants is



evident, for example, in the discussion of the results presented




in Table 19, where it was stated that the hypothesis of declining





-------
                                -109-






left unstated, the perceptive reader will have recognized that




neither are the table's results inconsistent with increasing




house age (HSAGE) or decreasing income (TCINC).  Only a theoretical




argument can provide a basis for ascertaining whether individual




householder differences in sensitivity to a:Lr pollution dosages




are wholly caused by differences in the actual disutility



people attach to air pollution ("tastes"), or whether these



sensitivity differences are due in part to householder income




differences or differences in some other factor.  The issue's




importance becomes apparent when one recognizes that income



determined sensitivity implies that a change in income causes a




change in the householder's willingness to pay for cleaner air




locations relative to other goods.  This, in turn, can bring about




changes in urban spatial configurations since it can imply that



prices of clean air locations will, independently of changes in



pollution dosages, change relative to the prices of locations




having greater air pollution dosages.




     Many implications for urban spatial configurations follow




immediately from the study's theoretical and empirical conclusion




that land values are more sensitive to variations in air pollution



dosages than are property values.  For example, on the basis of




this conclusion, any increase in air pollution dosages is held to




-------
                                -110-






equilibrium is established in which bundles of other characteristics




are substituted for bundles of housing characteristics and overall




property values are reduced, with the price of land bundles being




affected more than the price of nonland bundles.  Under a broad




range of conditions, one would expect land bundles to be substituted




for nonland bundles.  The new equilibrium could thus be described




as being relatively more land intensive.  Since a new equilibrium




is supposed to have been established, one might ask if this new




equilibrium is stable — particularly when the household sufferer




from air pollution dosages is treated as a more or less passive




observer of the passing air pollution  scene.




     As was earlier noted, a treatment of the householder as a




completely passive observer implies that the only argument in the




function which generates the sufferer's expectations about future




dosages is some history of realized dosages.  In short, the new




equilibrium land use pattern resulting from a change in dosages




is based only upon a change in a dosage history resulting from




the preexisting land use pattern.  But associated with each




locational equilibrium could be a unique configuration of air




pollution generating sources and dosages.  For example, a less




dense population distribution over space could change the




individually perceived price of automobile relative to mass





-------
                                -Ill-






increased transportation costs as individually perceived would




be greater than the individually perceived benefits of relocation




is worth investigation.




     Furthermore, greater population dispersal at least over some




substantial lange of an index of dispersal would seem to imply a




greater number of individual pollution sources, each of which emits




a relatively small quantity of pollutants.  Thus, given the quite




reasonable assumption that the cost of achieving a given reduction in




a given quantity of total emissions varies directly with the number




of emission sources, the marginal cost of air pollution control




could conceivably increase rather than decrease with increased air




pollution dosages.  That is, it might be that over some range Df




increasing land-nonland housing bundle ratios, air pollution is




increased and the marginal cost of attaining and maintaining a




given absolute pollution reduction increases.  The latter increase




in cost could occur because greater numbers of pollution sources




imply reduced economies of scale in emitter control equipment and




greater outlays on control agency policing and information services.




In any case, from this and the previous two or three paragraphs, it




should be obvious that considerations of household locational




behavior with respect to air pollution can under quite reasonable




conditions influence the supply of air pollution, optimal air




pollution control strategies, and the general pattern of urban





-------
                              -112-



     Estimation.  The offer functions for bundles of housing


characteristics presented in this study are representative of all


previous attempts to estimate cross-sectional housing demand


models in which the offer price is a function of various attributes


of the house in question and the householder's income.  In other


words, the present study has by no means exhausted the possibility


of improving the basic theory by experimenting with formulations
                                                                 t

differing from previous formulations in terms of the explanatory


variables included, in terms of the functional form in which these


variables enter the models, and in terms of the techniques employed


for obtaining the estimates.  Empirical insights acquired by


statistical means can provide direct information about functional


forms and variable weights.  This information can often be used

to strengthen and to extend the insights obtainable by deductive


theoretical reasoning.  One requires two legs to walk.


     Most of the statistical experimentation suggested here can be


carried out with the Chicago data employed for the present study.


Thus additional checks on the declining marginal damage hypothesis


can be obtained by introducing a form for the pollution variables


giving greater weight to low dosages and lesser weight to high

dosages.  Assuming no problems of nonorthogonality with other ex-


planatory variables, that set of weights which maximizes the


"t-values" of the pollution variables would, in statistical terms,



-------
                                -113-






     Various specifications of the offer function in terms of




explanatory variables included and functional forms can be




evaluated in terms of the accuracy with which they forecast offer




price.  Consider a situation in which the actual values of offer




price are denoted by COSTS, the forecasts of COSTS generated by




one specification as f,, and the forecasts of another specification




as f2-  In Hoel  57  is found a "t-test" which permits the




predictive ability of f« to be tested against that of f .  In




effect, the regression






             COSTS - fl = a + b (f2 - fj)






is calculated.  A significantly positive b implies that f2 *-s




statistically a better choice than f,.  A significantly negative b




 in the regression






             COSTS - f2 = a1 +  b1 (fl - f2)






would tend to reenforce this finding.  In this manner a ranking of




specifications can be established yielding some idea of the




tradeoffs involved between forecast accuracy and the costs of




additional data collection and computation which underlie more




detailed and complex specifications.




     Various manipulations of the data employed in this study gave





-------
                                -114-






pollution coefficients because of the improper exclusion of




explanatory variables.  However, it must be admitted that these




manipulations were applied to a very small number of variables.




About 150 of the approximately 180 nonpollution variables for




which infonuation had been collected were eliminated in the study's



very earliest stages.  The criterion employed for summary dismissal




was simply an inspection of simple correlation coefficients for




offer price and the variable; and the signs and levels of




statistical significance in a relatively small number of regressions




combined with some prior knowledge based on "feel", economic theory,




and previous empirical studies of the extent to which particular




variables can be expected to contribute to offer price.  This




partly ad hoc procedure is unlikely to exclude explanatory variables




of any real Importance if householders do in fact always make their




evaluations in terms of these individual variables.  The problems




of multicollinearity and losses in degrees of freedom which these




variables separate inclusion would entail would be very costly in




statistical terms.  Nevertheless, though these variables may




individually contribute little to an explanation of variations in




offer price, certain combinations and collections of them may have



a good deal to offer.  If householders make their evaluations in




terms of a scalar index measure of these combinations, then certain





-------
                                -115-






excluded.  The pollution coefficients obtained in the present




study may therefore be biased.  According to Kane  58 p. 277  ,




a factor analysis can reduce the large group of variables which



may generate this possible bias into a potentially smaller set of




reference variables or factors.  If the resulting factors are




orthogonal, they can then be employed as explanatory variables in




specifications employing the standard regression procedures.




     A further source of possible and as yet untested bias in the




pollution coefficients enters if one suggests that offer price




and the pollution variables are somehow jointly determined.  Similar



suggestions could be advanced for the school quality and mortgage



duration variables employed in this study.  For example, one could



construct an argument consistent with economic theory in which the




perceived cost to an air pollution control agency of bringing




about a given absolute reduction in the emissions from a given




set of sources varies inversely with the value of the property being




effected.  People who own valuable property are presumed to be




able and willing to put more pressure on an air pollution control



agency.  Though this ability and willingness is undoubtedly




usually captured by inclusion of an explanatory variable for



permanent income, it is not beyond belief that air pollution




control authorities become more upset about a given dollar





-------
                                -116-




                             25
in a low property value area.    If the costs the authorities



feel are in any way related to the level of property values



independently of the residents' income levels, then the problem of



simultaneity with its accompanying biases enters.  The writer is



strongly inclined to dismiss as rather fanciful the real importance


                       26
of this source of bias.    Nevertheless, simultaneity does constitute



one basis for criticizing the results of the present study.  As



Goldberger   36, pp. 329-336  shows, an estimating procedure known



as two-stage least squares provides a means of ridding the



pollution coefficients of whatever simultaneous equations bias



may exist in them.



     The prime estimation difficulty associated with the present



study has been the failure to employ a way of estimating lagged



responses to air pollution dosages which had even a moderate



degree of reliability.  Provision of these estimates was initially



envisioned as one of the study's central purposes.  In addition



to further time-consuming and costly attempts to produce a



nonlinear distributed lag program of the genre discussed in the



previous section, other less complex means of estimating these



lags suggest themselves.  For example, a straight time-series



analysis using "canned" distributed lag programs could be performed



if one was to use some measure of central tendency of the




-------
                                -117-



possess adequate degrees of freedom to permit this, though, of

course, the usual aggregation problems would exist.  Furthermore,

different: properties would contribute to each month's average.  A

central tenet of time-series analysis would therefore be violated.

     Nevertheless, a time-series analysis of the above sort if

supplemented by pooled cross-sectional estimates employing simple

lag forms could produce a collection of estimates establishing with

a fair degree of confidence the upper and lower bounds of the

typical lag's magnitude.  For example, the weight given past

pollution dosages in the formation of a householder's expectations

about future dosages may be made some polynomial function of the

elapsed time between the dosage and the present.  Though there

would be some loss in degrees of freedom, ordinary least squares
                                                a-fbt
procedures can readily deal with such terms as p    , where p

represents the dosage, t is elapsed time, and a and b are

parameters to be estimated.  Taking the logarithm of this term

yields   ( a 4- bt) Inp  which is identical to  a Inp + bt Inp ,

an expression that is linear in the parameters.  In effect, pooled

cross-sectional pollution coefficients would be expressed as

functions of time.

     Alternatively, rather than continuing to attempt directly

to establish the lag terms in the offer price equation, one could


-------
                                -118-




past pollution dosages would be obtained.  This scalar value would


then be  entered directly into the offer price equation.  Alternative


first-step weighting schemes would be employed until pollution


coefficients were obtained in the second-step that met "suitable"


conditions.  The conditions of suitability in this utterly ad hoc


estimation procedure would presumably be some mix of intuitive


reasonableness, t-values for the pollution coefficients, and the

                       —2
offer price equation's R .  However, it should be explicitly


recognized that it would be the form of the lag rather than the


hypothesis of adaptive expectations which would constitute the


theoretical ad hockery.  That is, the existence of a lag is


readily  justified in economic theory, but there is at present no


basis in that theory as it applies to air pollution damages for


a priori specification of the lag's form.  Regardless of the


estimating procedures one onploys, one at present is dependent


upon the data to give insight into the lag form.  The truth about


the lag  form is supposed to jump from the data.  If one employs


the quarterly or annual dosages found in the Chicago data, some


indication of the nature of the lag form could probably be obtained


without  incurring great expense in computer time or programming.


     Empirical Issues.  The questions raised in the subsections


dealing with theoretical and estimation issues all have their



-------
                                -119-






work to be done calling for no substantive extensions in theoretical




frameworks or estimation procedures.  Since many of the empirical




applications raised in the theory and estimation subsections are




immediately apparent, this subsection will address itself only to




those applications not readily apparent as well as more or less




strictly empirical questions that have not yet been given any




attention.




     A fair number of studies of the covariation between air




pollution dosages and property or land values now exist.  Without




exception, those studies employing the Lancaster formulation of the




damage function have found that dosages and property values are




significantly and inversely related.  Nevertheless, these studies




indicate that there are some differences in sensitivities among




cities.  The damage elasticities in Chicago, for example, appear to




be somewhat higher than those found for other cities.  The




theoretical framework of the present paper implies that at least




a part of these differences in marginal damages and damage




elasticities is attributable to differences in air pollution




dosages.  However, it could be that the factors which determine




pollution sensitivity differ among cities.  For example, if




increasing air pollution dosages do in fact cause land to be




substituted for improvements in the production of bundles of





-------
                                -120-






nonpolluting transport alternatives can be expected to suffer the




smaller air pollution damages.  One can readily conceive of property




value studies of a large number of cities where intercity comparisons




would be made of land and property damage functions and responsiveness




to uncertainty about air pollution dosages.  The study's prime




objective would be to acquire insight into the causes of these




differences among cities.  The term "acquire insight" rather than




"explain" is employed because it seems unlikely to the present writer




that a formal process of initially deriving propositions from




economic theory and then subjecting them to formal tests would




prove especially productive.  This  is simply because there are an




extremely large number of causes that are consistent with this




theory.  Instead, after an initial empirical identification of those




differences that do exist, economic theory can be employed to




determine which of these existing differences can in fact explain




differences in air pollution sensitivities.




     On a less ambitious scale, several other empirical studies can




be conceived.  We do no more than list them here.  As a check on




the conclusions that were drawn from the regressions in which land




values and property values were employed as dependent variables, the




value of improvements alone should also be employed as a dependent




variable.




     All property value studies have used only suspended particulates





-------
                               -121-






studies should be attempted in which additional types of pollutants




are introduced.  There is no necessary reason why these two types of




pollutants constitute good proxies for the many other pollutant




types.




     The measures used in the present study of negative influences



upon property value other than air pollution are not the best




imaginable.  If the measurement errors in such variables as NHAGE




or CRIMX are systematically correlated with the air pollution var-




iables , statistical biases can be introduced into the damage




estimates.  Some thought could be given to devising better measures.




One possibility, which under certain assumptions about the data's



nature is already available in the Chicago FHA data, is the use of




fire and property damage rates as indicators of the joint effects




of neighborhood threats and fire and police protection upon a



property's value.




     Summary and Conclusions on Desirable Research Extensions






     A discussion of desirable research extensions implies that




the possible extensions differ in the extent of their desir-



ability.  Their desirability can be ranked according to the




contributions each can make to the fundamental problems of interest



as well as the costs of carrying out these extensions.  But, as





-------
                                -122-






Any ranking of possible extensions thus requires some fairly




 'substantial attempt to explain and defend it.  In the present




context, the returns accruing to such an effort are difficult to




identify.  Accordingly, this subsection restrains itself and limits




its remarks to listing in tabular form the topics presented in the




research extensions section.  Appended to each topic is a remark




indicating whether or not the empirical version of the topic can




be studied employing the data used in the present study.  Since




data is costly and time-consuming to collect, any topic whose




empirical version can be studied using the existing Chicago data




has at least one positive advantage relative to alternative topics.




     t...  Theoretical issues




         1)  Weakening the conditions for the declining marginal



             damage function—no additional data required.




         2)  Construction of supply function for bundles of housing




             characteristics—most, but not all, data already



             collected.



         3)  Damage functions for increasing and decreasing air



             pollution dosages—careful inspection of Chicago air




             pollution data necessary, but likely this data would




             be suitable.




         4)  Determinants of sensitivity to air pollution dosages—





-------
                           -123-






    5)  Impact of air pollution dosages on urban spatial




        configurations—substantial new data collection efforts




        required.




B.  Estimation—no new data collection efforts are required for




        any topic in this subsection,.




C.  Empirical issues




    1)  Differences in pollution sensitivities among cities—




        large and expensive new data collection efforts required.




    2)  Value of improvements as a dependent variable—no new data




        collection efforts required.




    3)  Improved measures of neighborhood influences upon




        property values—new data collection efforts are required.




    4)  Additional pollutant types—new data collection efforts





-------
                                -124-






                             FOOTNOTES




1.  It is assumed throughout this essay that the compensating




variation and air pollution damages are synonymous.  The reader is




warned that willingness to pay is not necessarily identical to what




a receptor rrould have to be paid in order to be willing to accept




a little more air pollution.




2.  The expression "well-behaved" is a euphimisra for some rather




strong regularity conditions.  In particular,   (zn)     ^Zi2-*  ^




z.,   z.o for all i and Zjo^O ^or at ^east one *••  Furthermore,  as




the offer function is derived in Appendix B,  must have strictly




positive first order partial derivatives and continuous second




order partial derivatives everywhere.  Nevertheless, this representation




is weaker than is usual, for, as Lancaster   14, pp. 156-157   shows,




the formulation of   employed here need not be convex .




3.  For more on this point, see Appendices A and B.




4.  Since our offer function reads c = c(z * y), this view of the




identity of offer prices for housing and consumer expenditures for




housing could mean that we have a greater number of different




characteristics than we have price observations on goods.  That is,




any arbitrarily specified bundle of characteristics could be




embodied in more than one good.  Therefore no unique utility




maximizing housing location could be discovered.  However, as





-------
                                -125-






and convex, an n-diraensional slice of  (z), where n   r, will have




the same general properties as   (z) defined in r-dintensions.




In any case, the problem of excessive characteristics does not




seem relevant here.  Kain and Quigley  17  could enumerate no




more than twenty-one characteristics making a statistically




significant contribution to housing offer prices.




     5.  The developments in this and the succeeding subsection




owe much to readings of Lind  8  , Muth  27  , and Alonso  28




     6.  The formal reasoning underlying these statements can be




developed from Brandow  29  and Muth  30




     7.  This does not preclude ex post adjustments of behavior




(adaptations of expectations) to realized errors in forecasts.  The




necessary conditions for the validity of certainty equivalence are




ably presented in Malinvaud  18.




     8.  The latter approach, termed the time-state preference




approach to uncertainty, applies a discount rate to future




contingent claims, where the rate discounts for futurity and for




probability.  A detailed presentation of the approach is available




in Hirshleifer  19  .




     9.  The following development leans very heavily upon the




presentations in Levy  20  and Hanoch and Levy  21




     10.  For an excellent short review of the principal features




and implications of these alternative criteria, see Tisdell





-------
                                -126-




     11.  Data made available to the writer from the Chicago


offices of the FHA indicate more or less constant marginal costs


for a wide variety of structural characteristics.  The sign of

 3
  c    o  would thus be positive when it is recognized that
      z

attempts to .alter neighborhood characteristics involve the formation


of coalitions of households.  It is generally thought that increasing


the number of coalition members implies increasing marginal costs of


coalition formation.


     12.  See Nerlove  10, pp. 22-23  .


     13.  Past and present administrators of the Chicago Air


Pollution Control District have described the District's sampling


and control program in a number of published papers and reports.  A


description is available, for example, in Stanley  37  .  Additional


information on the District's sampling and control program as well


as the general nature of Chicago's air pollution problem is


presented in Upham  39  , Johnson  40  , Stanley and Heller  41  ,


and Northeastern Illinois Planning Commission  42


     14.  The necessary meteorological data could not be obtained


from the Chicago Air Pollution Control District.


     15.  A more thorough development of these points is available


in Green  15, pp. 99-103  .


     16.  The following provides a .notion of the diversity of the



-------
                                -127-






improvement's exterior had a fiberboard finish, the inclusion of




a dishwasher in the sale, the type of water service, wife's age,




rate of commitments for felonies by neighborhood males from 1958




to 1962, the percentage of pupils in Sept. 1967 at the nearest




elementary school below national reading norms, the floor space




in the second closest shopping center, the zoning classification,




and the seat miles of mass transit service available at the nearest




rapid transit facility.




     17.  The economic-theoretic nature of the relation between




permanent income and offer prices is presented in Reid  45




     18.  This is a bit of an overstatement since Ridker and Henning




  2   carry out some residualization procedures because of perceived




colline'arity between their measures of permanent income and air




pollution.  Three comments are in order about their results.  First,




their air pollution data was grouped in that air pollution dosages




over fairly wide intervals were assigned unique single values.  This




grouping would tend to increase the correlation between the air




pollution and the income variables.  Second, the air pollution




damage coefficients Ridker and Henning obtained using a




residualized permanent income measure as a regressor were within the




standard error of the pollution coefficient when the income measure




was not residualized.  Third, as was noted in Anderson and Crocker





-------
                               -128-



or unresidualized, reflected the effect of mistakenly entering the

median fejnily income of a single census tract as zero.

     19. - It is worth noting here that an application for the t-test

to any of the air pollution coefficients presented in this section
                                                    /\
means, given that it carries the correct sign, that b is signifi-

cantly different from zero.  We specify as the null-hypothesis the

claim of some who argue that residential property values will not

register any air pollution damages whatsoever.  Thus, we are test-

ing for coefficients permitting rejection of this null hypothesis.

In short, we wish to follow a testing strategy which minimizes the

chance of accepting the false hypothesis that an air pollution coef-

ficient is significantly different from zero when it actually is not,

     20.  One coul  perhaps ease this problem by employing an

interaction term such as In (PRT66) (SUL66) in the regressions.

However, the definition of the interaction term requires the ex

ante and in this case ad hoc assignment of a weight to each

pollutant.  Thus the choice was made in this study to employ

pollution measures which permit realistic interpretations in

ordinary regressions, though these measures raise doubts about the

use of analysis of covariance.  The cost of this choice was the

foregoing of an arbitrary assignment of weights to each pollutant


-------
                                -129-



relation to any real situation could be interpreted in any manner


the reader saw fit.


     21.  This statement is compromised by our earlier statement


about the validity of the use of the analysis of covariance in a


context wheie the pollutants are synergic.


     22.  One should note that the influence of variance in air


pollution dosages upon expected utility could conceivably be
                                            i

non-linear in the variables and in the parameters.  The earlier


discussion  of the cubic utility function could be made to suggest


that the impact of the second moment upon expected utility varies


with the level of air pollution dosages.  Specifically, the


behavior could change from risk-aversion to risk-preference as


dosages fall, given that the marginal utility of less air pollution


is always positive.


     23.  This program was written especially for this project by


R. J. Anderson, Jr., formerly of Purdue University's Department of


Economics.


     24.  An attempt was made to avoid the problems in the


distributed lag estimating procedure by entering as separate


explanatory variables the mean annual dosages of each pollutant


for the three years immediately preceding 1967.  However, the


collinearity of these measures was so great as to render the



-------
                               -130-






     25.  If ability and willingness to impose pressures upon the



control agency is a function of permanent income and if offer price



or property value is a function of permanent income, then the prob-



lem is one of the improper exclusion of permanent income from the



list of explanatory variables rather than the simultaneity of



property value and the air pollution measures.



     26.  A major argument ,for dismissal is that even if property



values do have an independent impact upon air pollution dosages,



there is likely to be a substantial lag between the control



agency's perception of cost and its completion of the action to



reduce dosages.  The observed pollution in the current period would



therefore be predetermined, i.e., the simultaneity problem would




-------
                              -131-
                          BIBLIOGRAPHY
 1.  Anderson, R.J.,  Jr.,  and T.D.  Crocker,  "Air  Pollution and
     Residential Property  Values,"  Urban Studies  (forthcoming).

 2.  Ridker, R.G., and J.A.  Henning,  "The Determinants  of  Residential
     Property Values  with  Special Reference  to Air Pollution," The
     Review of Economics and Statistics, 49,  (May, 1967),  pp.  246-257,

 3.  Ridker, R.G., Economic  Costs o_f  Air Pollution,  New York:
     Frederick A. Praeger, (1967).

 4.  Zerbe, R.O., Jr., The Economics  of Air  Pollution:   A  Cost-
     Benefit Approach, Toronto:   Ontario Department  of  Public Health,
     (July, 1969).

 5.  Wieand, K.F., Property  Values  and the Demand for Clean Air:
     Cross Section Study for St.  Louis. Unpublished  Ph.D.  Dis-
     sertation, Washington University, (1970).

 6.  Peckham, B.W., Air Pollution Damages to Residential Properties
     in Philadelphia, Unpublished manuscript, Raleigh,  N.C.:
     Division of Economic  Effects Research,  National Air Pollution
     Control Administration, (1970).

 7.  Strotz, R.H., The Use of_ Land  Rent Changes to_ Measure the
     Welfare Benefits £f_ Land Improvement, Evans ton, 111.:
     Department of Economics, Northwestern University,  (July,  1966).
     Dittoed.

 8.  Lind, R.G., Land Market Equilibrium and the  Measurement of
     Benefits from Urban Programs,  A paper presented at the CUE
     Conference, Univ. of  Chicago,  (September 11-12, 1970).

 9.  Samuelson, P.A., Foundations of  Economic Analysis, Cambridge:
     Harvard University Press, (1947).

10.  Nerlove, M., Distributed Lags  and Demand Analysis, Washington,
     D.C.:  USGPO, Agriculture Handbook No.  141,  (June,1958).

11.  Muth, J.F., "Rational Expectations and  the Theory  of  Price

-------
                               -132-
  12.  Cox, D.R., "Prediction by Exponentially Weighted Moving
       Averages and Related Methods," Journal £f_ the Royal Statistical
       Society. Series B, 23, (1961).

  13.  Koyck, L.M., Distributed Lags and Investment Analysis,
       Amsterdam:  North-Holland Publishing Co., (1954).

  14.  Lancaster, K.J., "A New Approach to Consumer Theory,"
       .Journal of Political Economy, 74 (April, 1966), pp. 132-157.

\ 15.  creen, H.A.J., Aggregation in Economic Analysis, Princeton:
       Princeton University Press, (1964).

  16.  Coldman, S.M., and H. Uzawa, " A Note on Separability in
       Demand Analysis," Econometrica, 32, (1964),  pp. 387-398.

  •17.  Kain, J.F., and J. M. Quigley, "Measuring the Value of  Housing
       Quality," Journal gf the American Statistical Association, 65,
       (June, 1970), pp. 532-548.
i
 .18.  Malinvaud, E., "First Order Certainty Equivalence,"
 •      Econometrica, 37, (October, 1969), 706-718.

  I 19.  Hirshleifer, J., "Investment Decision Under  Uncertainty:
       Choice-Theoretic Approaches," The Quarterly  Journal of_
       Economics, 79, (November, 1965), pp.509-536.

  20.  Levy, H., "A Utility Function Depending on the First Three
       Moments," The Journal of Finance, 24, ( September, 1969),
       pp. 715-719.

  21.  Hanoch, G., and H. Levy, "Efficient Portfolio Selection with
       Quadratic and Cubic Utility," The Journal £f_ Business,  43,
       (April, 1970), pp. 181-189.

  22.  Richter, M.K., "Cardinal Utility, Portfolio  Selection,  and
       Taxation." Review of Economic Studies. 27, (1959), pp.  152-166.

  23.  Tisdell, C.A., The Theory of Price Uncertainty, Production
  !     and Profit, Princeton, N.J.:  Princeton University Press, (1968)
  1 s
  '24.  Wald, A., Statistical Decision Functions, New York:  John Wiley

-------
                             -133-
25.  Illldrcth, C., "Problems of Uncertainty in Farm Planning,"
     Journal of Farm Economics, 39, (December, 1957),  pp.  1430-1441.

26.  de Leeuw, F., The Supply of Rental Housing,  Washington,  B.C.:
     The Urban Institute, Working Paper 112-11, (August  7,  1970).

27.  Muth, R.F., Cities and Housing.  Chicago:   The University of
     Chicago Press, (1969).

28.  Alonso, W., Location and Land Use, Cambridge:   Harvard
     University Press, (1964) .

29.  Brandow, G.E., "Demand for Factors and Supply of  Output  in a
     Perfectly Competitive Industry," Journal  £f_  Farm  Economics,
     44, (August, 1962), pp. 895-899.

30.  Muth, R.F., "The Derived Demand  Curve for a  Productive
     Factor and the Industry Supply Curve," Oxford Economic  Papers,
     16, (July, 1964), pp. 221-234.

31.  Babcock, L.R., Jr., "A Combined  Pollution Index for Measurement
     of Total Air Pollution," Journal ££ the Air  Pollution Control
     Association. 20, (October, 1970), p"p. 653-659.

32.  U.S. Bureau of the Census, U.S.  Censuses  o_f  Population and
     Housing:  1960, Chicago, Illinois, Final  Report PHC (l)-26
     (Washington, D.C.:  U.S. Government Printing Office,  1962).

33.  Kish, L., and J. B. Lansing, "Response Errors in  Estimating
     the Value of Homes," Journal o£  the American Statistical
     Association, 49, (September, 1954), pp. 520-538.

34.  Booz, Allen & Hamilton, Inc., Study to Determine  Residential
     Soiling Costs £f Particulate Air Pollution,  A Report  to  NAPCA
     for Contract No. CPA-22-69-103 (Washington,  D.C., October  15,
     1970).

35.  Michelson, I., and B. Tourin, "Comparative Method for
     Studying the Costs of Air Pollution," Public Health Reports,
     81, (June, 1966), pp. 505-511.

36.  Goldberger, A.A., Econometric Theory, New York:  John Wiley

-------
                             -13U-
37.  Stanley, W.J.,  Chicago's Air Resource Planning Program,
     Paper No. 68-172, Presented at the 61st Annual Meeting of
     the Air Pollution Control Association, St.  Paul,  Minn.
     (June 27, 1968).

38.  Alexander, H.W.,  Elements of Mathematical Statistics,  New
     York:  John Wiley & Sons, Inc.,  (1961).

39.  Upham, J.B., "Atmospheric Corrosion Studies in Two
     Metropolitan Areas,"  Journal £f the Air Pollution Control
     Association, 17,  (June, 1967), pp. 398-402.

40.  Johnson, K.L.,  "Citizen Complaints of Air Pollution in
     Northeastern Illinois,"  Journal £f the Air Pollution  Control
     Association. 18,  (June, 1968), pp. 399-400.

41.  Stanley, W.J.,  and A.N. Heller,  "Air Resource Management
     in the Chicago  Metropolitan Area," Journal  o£ the Air  Pollution
     Control Association. 16, (October, 1966), pp. 536-540.

42.  Northeastern Illinois Planning Commission,  Managing the Air
     Resource in Northeas tern Illinois, Technical Report No.  6,
     Chicago, Illinois:  Northeastern Illinois Planning Commission,
     (August, 1967).

43.  U.S.  Bureau of  the Census, 1967  Census of Governments, Vol. 2:
     Taxable Property  Values, Washington, D.C.:   U.S.  Government
     Pointing Office,  (1968).

44.  DeVise, P., Chicago's Widening Color Gap, Chicago, Illinois:
     Interuniversity Social Research  Committee,  Report #2,
     (December, 1967).

45.  Grigsby, W.G.,  Housing Markets and Public Policy, Philadelphia:
     University of Pennsylvania Press, (1963).

46.  Reid, M.G., Housing and Income,  Chicago: University of Chicago
     Press, (1962).

47.  Lee,  T.H., "Housing and Permanent Income:   Tests  Based on  a
     Three-Year Reinterview Survey,"  The Review  of_ Economics and

-------
                            -135-
48.  Malone, J.R., "The Capital Expenditure for Owner-Occupied
     Housing:  A Study of Determinants,"  The Journal of  Business,
     39, (July, 1966), pp. 359-365.

49.  Atkinson, L.J., "Factors Affecting the Purchase Value  of
     New Homes,"  Survey of Current  Business, 46,  (August,  1966),
     pp.20-36.

50.  Crocker, T.D., "Some Economics  of Air Pollution Control,"
     Natural Resources Journal, 8,  (April, 1968),  pp. 236-258.

51.  Farrar, D.E., and R.R. Glauber, "Multicollinearity  in
     Regression Analysis:  The Problem Revisited,"  The  Review
     of Economics and Statistics,  49, (February, 1967),  pp.92-107.

52.  Shaw, C.R., and McKay, H.D.,  Juvenile Delinquency and  Urban
     Areas, Chicago:  The University of Chicago Press, (1969).

53.  George C. Olcutt & Co., Olcutt's Land Values  Blue Book £f_
     Chicago and Suburbs, Chicago;  George C. Olcutt & Co.,  (1969).

54.  City of Chicago Department of Development and Planning,
     Development Areas, 16 Vols.,  (1965-69).

55.  Havighurst, R.J., The Public  Schools of Chicago, Chicago:
     The Board of Education of the City of Chicago, (1964) .

56.  Tiao, G.C., and A.&. Goldberger, Testing Equality of
     Individual Regression Coefficients,  University of Wisconsin,
     Social Systems Research Institute, Workshop on the  Economic
     Behavior of Households, Paper 6201,  (February, 1962),  pp.  10.

57.  Hoel, P.G., "On the Choice of Forecasting Formulas,"
     Journal of the American Statistical  Association, U2 (19^7),
     pp. 605-611.

58.  Kane, E.J., Economic Statistics and  Econometrics, New  York:

-------
                   Appendix A









 Property Values and the Demand For Clean Air:




       Cross Section Study for St. Louis
                Kenneth F. Wieand
            A Paper Presented at the




Committee on Urban Economics Research Conference,





-------
                               A-l






Introduction




      It is widely recognized that urban dwellers cannot pay for




individual quantities of clean air and that they cannot, as




individuals, charge polluters for damages caused by their effluents.




Consequently, the control of pollution has passed into the hands




of governmental agencies which are often empowered to set air




quality standards and to enforce these standards by levying fines




or instituting legal action against violators.




      Officials in these agencies have discovered that the absence




of market determined prices and quantities of air quality prevents




them from determining the level of air quality where total




benefits accruing from cleaner air neither exceed nor fall short




of the required costs.  Because this information is necessary to




achieve an economically efficient use of resources, economists




have attempted to measure indirectly the revealed preference for




air quality.




      One strategy for determining the demand for air quality




argues that the negative effects of air pollution will be




capitalized into the site value of residential housing.  It follows




that the demand for clean air can be determined by comparing




differentials in property values in areas where pollution is high




with property values where pollution levels are low.  This paper




summarizes an attempt to test the hypothesis that air pollution





-------
                               A-2






equation is based upon a recent adaptation of the location model




first proposed by Thunen  [1] .  Because of the lack of historical




price data, the model is tested with data from a cross section of




census tracts in the St. Louis area.




      Ridker  [2]  and Crocker and Anderson  [3]  found a




significant relationship between pollution and housing expenditures




using the same data source as is used in the current study.  This




paper compares their studies to the one described here.






Pollution and the Price gf Land




      There is reason to believe that the property value-pollution




level relationship will accurately reflect the deleterious effects




of air pollution upon persons and property.  Although pollution



levels tend to be high in centers of production and population,




factors such as wind direction and industry location distribute




pollutants unevenly within surrounding housing markers.  If housing




consumers in a city recognize that pollution levels vary within




the housing market, and if they prefer areas of higher air quality,



sites in neighborhoods where pollution levels are low will be




bid up relative to sites  in neighborhoods where pollution




concentrations are higher.



      Because the concentration of air pollution is a characteristic




of the housing unit's location, the price for clean air will be





-------
                               A-3






illustrated by considering the investor who may build a house




either in an area where pollution is high or in an area where it




is low.  Presumably, nonland costs are similar at the two sites.




The investor will compare the discounted income streams of the




two sites.  He must subtract the added maintenance costs (or




more rapid deterioration of the structure) from the income stream




at the polluted site.  The difference in the discounted income




streams w-ill be the price differential that the investor must




pay for the site where pollution is low.




      The appropriate model for testing the pollution-property




value relationship can therefore be written P. * P., (x, , ...Xj,, AP)




where P, is the per unit price of land,  x^ ,...xn are determinants



of land prices, and AP is an index of air pollution.






The Price £f_ Land and the Price £f Housing




      As in most urban residential areas, the number of empty




lots in the St. Louis housing market relative to all sites is




negligible.  Therefore, the price of land is not observable.



Studies such as the one discussed here attempt to use the unit




price of housing as a proxy for land prices.  Housing prices are



determined by the price of land and by the prices of nonland



factors.  Assuming that the housing market is competitive, and that




households maximize profits at each site, the price of housing





-------
                               A-4






fact, Equation (1) relates housing expenditures to factor inputs.




      (1)  PhH = P! L + PnN




where Ph is the per unit price of housing, H is the quantity of




housing, P, is the price of land, L is the quantity of land, and




P  and N are the per unit price and the quantity of all nonland




factors.




      Assumptions of competition and profit maximization imply




that a change in housing quantity will equal the sum of changes



in land and nonland factors multiplied by their marginal




productivities.  Therefore, upon differentiating Equation (1)




we derive




      (2) HdPfo » LdPj^ + NdPn




      Equation  (2) suggests that the price of housing will vary



directly with the price of land.  The price of housing is,



therefore, an appropriate proxy for the price of land.






Total Expenditures, Unit Price, and Land Use Intensity




      A major difference between the present study and the work of




Ridker and of Anderson and Crocker is in the choice of die




variable representing the price of housing.  The latter two studies




utilized the average rent and average market value statistics



reported in Census of Population and Housing. 1960 as their




dependent variables, while the author employed these same




-------
                                A-5
in tens i ty .
     Average rents and housing prices arise from transfers of
housing services between economic units.  In all transactions
involving housing services, both those involving rentals over a
period of time and those involving transfers of ownership, the
total price is a multiple of the price per unit that the services
can command, P^, times the quantity of housing services that are
involved  in the transaction H.
     In other words, average rents and average market values
are not measures of the unit price of housing, P, , but of total
family expenditures on housing, P. H.  It can be shown that total
family expenditures may move inversely with respect to the unit
price of housing, if the quantity of housing consumed, H, changes
in response to the change in Pi..  This fact can be demonstrated by
taking the derivative of P.H with respect to P, .
                          n                   h
     (3)     dPhH     HdPh  +  PhdH
     or
             dP H
             7~-  =
             dph
where e = price elasticity of demand
If e is equal to -1, a change in P^ will leave total expenditures
unchanged.  If e is less than -1, total expenditures will vary
inversely with changes in P, .  Recent research suggests that, in
the case of individual units, e may be -1 or smaller.—
_!/  Richard F. Muth, Cities and Housing, (Chicago:  University of

-------
                               A-6

Therefore, PnH is not an adequate surrogate for  P. .

      The use by past writers of family expenditures  as  a  surrogate

for unit price may result from an implicit assumption that the

quantity of housing can be held constant between units by  the

addition to the list of regressors of variables  which measure the

quantity of housing.  The quantity, H, of housing services depends

upon floor space, layout and room design, materials used in

construction of the unit, site size, and a number of  other factors.

A reasonably complete list of the components of  H has been compiled

by Kain and Quigley  [4] .  If these data were available,  they

could perhaps be added to the list of regressors to hold variation

of H constant.  The 1960 Census did not make available the

necessary detail, however, and H is not held constant.

      Civen an additional piece of information,  the problems

encountered in using household expenditures can  be avoided.  Muth

 [5] has shown that the intensity of land use will vary  directly

with the price of land, hence with the price of  housing, P^.  To

briefly reconstruct his proof, return to Equation (1)  and  divide

both sides by L.
           PhH
      <*>—'i *-£-'.

Taking the derivative of Equation (4)  in natural logs, one can


-------
                                A-7
     (5)     dlnPhH

             -  =  1 + fn 6dlnPn
                   f., = factor share of land



                   f  = share of nonland factors
                    n


                      = elasticity of substitution



*JL
 L    will vary directly with the price of land, provided that



the cost of nonland factors is constant throughout the labor



market, because 6, f , and f, are positive.  If 6 is



approximately 0.75 and the share of land is about 5 percent,



relative changes in PQH will be about fifteen times the size of
relative change in P^, and about the same magnitude as changes


      21

in PI»~



     The primary measure of land use intensity employed in this



paper was derived by multiplying average rentals plus 0.01 of owner



estimated market values in each census tract by the number of each



type of unit in the tract.  (In the real estate profession 0.01 is



the conversion rate used to appraise the rental of homes given their



market value.)  This figure measures the total monthly expenditure



on housing in each census tract.  The land area of each tract was



computed, and a land use map was used to net out industrial and

-------
                               A-8






commercial acreage.  Total monthly expenditure on housing was




then divided by the residential land area measured in acres to




arrive at monthly rent per acre.  This variable, measured in




natural logs, is namedVALAND.  VALAND is similar to the variable




used by Muth in a study for south Chicago [ 6] .  The lists of




regressors used in the two studies are also quite alike, except




for different measures of the age of housing and for the




addition of the pollution variables in the present study.




Predictably the two sets of results are quite similar.




      A measure of average expenditures on housing (VALHOU),




similar to that used by Ridker and by Crocker and Anderson, was




also utilized as a dependent variable in an attempt to compare




the performance of the independent variables in the three studies.






Determinants of the Intensity of Land Use




      The independent variables used to try to explain variance




in VALAND were the percent of standard units in a census tract




(STDPER), average age of housing in the census tract (AVGAGE),



percent of units built before 1920 in the tract (BEF20), percent



white population in the tract (WHITE), average income in the




tract (INCOME), distance in miles from the central business



district (DISCED), a dummy for proximity to major highways (HIWAY),




a dummy for tracts in East St. Louis, 111. (ESL), a dummy





-------
                               A-9






dummy for proximity to Industry (INDUS), and a dummy for proximity




to commercial areas (COMM).




      The first three variables were intended to explain the




variance in VALAND resulting from changes in the unit price and




quantity of tlte nonland portion of housing services.  STDPER was




included to isolate tracts where housing units have large amounts




of deferred maintenance; theory suggests that the coefficient of




this variable is positive.  AVGAGE measured the change in land




use intensity over time.  Decreasing transportation costs over




time should make the coefficient of AVGAGE  positive, but it




could be negative if the variable picked up housing deterioration




in older units.  BEF20 measured technical change in newer housing




such as expanded electrical circuitry, and gas and electric




heating systems; the coefficient of BEF20 should be negative.




      The next two variables measured neighborhood effects.  The




unit price of housing services was expected to rise in high income




areas because of neighborhood amenities.  It has been argued both




that non-whites pay more and that they pay less than whites for




equal quantities of housing.  The coefficients of WHITE and




BOUND could not be prejudged.




      The final five variables defined the locational characteristics




of the housing in a tract.  Increased commuting costs tend to




cause housing prices to decline as distance from the CBD increases.





-------
                               A-10






with respect to VALAND, whereas decreased commuting time near




expressways should cause the coefficient of HIWAY to be positive.




Proximity to industry may either increase or decrease VALAND:




while commuting to work is easier, adverse external effects tend to




drive down housing prices.  Finally, units near commercial




centers should command a higher price.




      Data on sulphur pollutants and particulates are available



on a spatial basis for a number of large cities.  Ridker and




Crocker and Anderson included sulfation, measured as sulphur




trioxide, and suspended particulates, measured with hi-vol samplers,




in their models.  The paper under discussion utilized this




information along with measures of dustfall and sulphur dioxide.




      Like the other variables in the model, pollution levels vary




spatially.  Unlike the other variables, pollution concentrations




also fluctuate over time.  One can prove that the average



concentration of a pollutant for a given period of time will




accurately reflect the disutility of the pollutant's temporal




distribution only if the marginal disutility of pollution is




constant.  Because the effects of pollution become more noticeable




as concentrations increase, the assumption of constant marginal




disutility does not seem warranted.  Therefore, measures of the




variance of the temporal distribution were also included.  As




the inclusion of these measures did not improve the performance




-------
                               A-ll






variables are not presented here.




      In the following presentation of results PAR stands for




variables measuring suspended particulates, and S0~ represents




measures of sulphur trioxide.  Existing  data do not define either




particulates or sulphur for each census tract in the study area.



It was therefore necessary to estimate pollution levels for most




tracts.  Three methods of estimation were employed.  sPAR and




sSO-j are variables obtained from isopleths (lines of equal actual




value) found in t:he Interstate Air Pollution Study [7] .  If the




majority of a census tract lay between two isopleths, air




pollution in .the tract was assumed to equal the level prevailing




on the boundary of the isopleth furthest from the CBD.  These



variables are similar to the proxies used by Ridker and by Crocker




and Anderson.




      Pollution measured in this fashion resembles a step function




decreasing with distance from the CBD.  One would expect pollution




to decline continuously rather than in discrete jumps.  Therefore,




variables iSO^ and iPAR were estimated by interpolating in a



straight line between isopleths.  Finally, SO^ and PARm were derived



using data from isopleths, monitoring stations, and information on



wind direction.  803 and PARm are expected to be the most accurate




measures of the average levels of particulates and sulphur pollution





-------
                               A-12






Empirical Results and Conclusions




      Table I. reports the results obtained by regressing VALAND




against regressors other than the pollution variables.  All but




HIWAY have signs consistent with a priori  expectation, all but




BOUND, HIWAY, and COMM are significantly related to VALAND, and




the magnitudes of the coefficients are reasonable.




      Table II. lists the coefficients of the pollution variables.




INDUS, COMM, and BEF20 are correlated with the pollution variables,




For purposes of exposition, these three variables are omitted




from the estimating equation.




      The coefficients of pollution are negative in most cases




but are not significantly related to VALAND.  If either ESL or




STDPER is omitted from the estimating equation, the coefficients




of the pollution variables fall and become significant at the .05




level.  The author doubts that multicollinearity between pollution



and ESL and STDPER is responsible for the lack of a significant



relationship between pollution and VALAND for two reasons.  First,



the standard errors of the pollution variables do not fall when




ESL and STDPER are deleted from the equation.  Also, a subsample




of 86 observations was selected by dropping all tracts in East




St. Louis and all tracts where the percent of standard units was




small to determine whether ESL and STDPER obscured a significant




relationship between pollution and VALAND.  When the equation is




tested using the subsample, the pollution variables behave as they




-------
                               A-13






      Table III. lists the percentage changes in VALHOU and




VALAND implied by 10 percent changes in some of the independent




variables.  Examination of Table III. shows that the relationships




between VALHOU and the exogenous variables may be quite different




from the relationships between these variables and VALAND.  The




coefficients of INCOME in the VALHOU regressions imply that the




average value of housing in the study area is twice the size  of




the average yearly income, reflecting the fact that average




housing prices in the SMSA were about $12,000 in 1960, and that




average income was about $6,000.  This relationship obviously




reflects the fact that the elasticity of demand for housing is




greater than zero.  If relative changes in VALAND are fifteen times




the changes in the price of housing, the 7.5 percent change in




VALAND implies a 0.5 percent change in the price of housing.




Consider also the changes in VALHOU implied by a 10 percent




change in DISCED.  Three of the VALHOU regressions state that




expenditures increase with distance when we would expect price to




decline.  Positive distance coefficients are consistent with a




price elasticity of less than -1.  The VALAND regression implies,



on the other hand, that the price of land declines at 12 percent




per mile and therefore, that the price of housing falls by a




little less than 1 percent per mile.




      This paper concludes that, although there is reason to





-------
                               A-14






with levels of air pollution, average rentals, market prices, or




other measures of household expenditures are not adequate proxies




for the price of housing.  The output land ratio used in the study




summarized here is a suitable proxy for the price of housing.




When the output land ratio is regressed against levels of air




pollution and other determinants of housing prices, the regression




coefficients of the pollution variables are generally negative,




but are not significantly different from zero at the .05 level.




      The results of the study discussed above do not prove that




the effects of air pollution are not harmful to urban dwellers.




They do caution against using past findings to justify reductions





-------


A-15
Table I
Results of Regressing VALAND Against Variables
Other than Pollution Variables



Variable
STDPER
WHITE
AVGAGE
BEF20
INCOME
DISCED
INDUS
ESL
HIWAY
BOUND
COMM
R2
Constant
Coefficient Equation
(Standard Error) 4.2
0.59
(.20)
-0.22
(.10)
0.021
(.005)
-0.61
(.11)
0.6x10 "t
(.2xlO~ )
-0.116
(.023)
-0.24
( .064)
-0.75
(.11)
-0.10
(.064)
0.12
(.080)
0.091
(.077)
0.64
term 6.06

4.3
0.59
(.20)
-0.29
(.096)
0.021
(.005)
-0.61
(.11)
0.7xlO~
(.2x10 )
-0.122
(.023)
-0.26
(.061)
-0.74
(.11)



0.62
6.05
Degrees of
  freedom
126

-------
                               A-16

                             Table II

     Performance of Three Alternate Measures of Particulates
            and of Sulfur Trioxide in Explaining VALANDa

Variable
Sulfur Trioxide
S03
iS03
sS03
Particulates
PARro
iPAR
sPAR
Coefficient

+0.0036
-0.0790
-0.0870

-0.0015
-0.0011
-0.0012
a
Th"3 specification used is as
Standard Error

0.001
0.105
0.150

0.0013
0.0017
0.0021
follows: VALAND
R2

0.45
0.45
0.45

0.45
0.45
0.45
» f (pollution
variable. DISCED, STDPER, AVGAGE, INCOME, WHITE, ESL)


      Measured in milligrams/hundred cubic centimeters

     £

-------
                               A-17

                            Table III

CHANCE IN VALHOU AND VALAND RESULTING FROM A TEN PERCENT CHANGE IN
       SELECTED INDEPENDENT VARIABLES: COMPARISONS OF WIEAND
              RIDKER, AND CROCKER - ANDERSON STUDIES
Independent Variable


Depend end en t Variable
VAI.HOIT VALAND
Wieand
owned and
rented
Crocker - Anderson
owned rented
Ridker
owned
Wieand
owned and
rented
sS03
SPAR
INCOME
DISCED
Built before 1940
Condition
Percent Standard
Percent Dilapidated
WHITE
AVGAGE
Median Rooms
Constant (log,,)
R2 6
Degrees of freedom
-1.0

26.0
2.7**
-1.0**

5.1

-2.8


7.8
0.75
139.0
-2.0
-1.7
19.0
-4.0
-0.4


16.0
-1.2


3.5
0.76
236.0
-0.2**
-1.1
14.0
1.0**
-1.0


13.2
-0.8


-1.2
0.77
174.0
-0.8

20.0
1.3
-0.1





9.0
7.3
0.94
167.0
-0.9**
-1.2
7.5
-12.0


6.6

-2.3
8.0

6.1
0.66
139.0

-------
                               A-18
                           REFERENCES
1.  R.F. Muth, "Rural Urban Land Conversions," Econometrica,
    XXIX (January, 1961), 1-23; see also R.F. Muth, "The
    Spatial Structure of the Housing Market," Regional Science
    Association;  Papers and Proceedings, VII (1961), 207-20;
    R.F. Muth, "Variation of Population Density and Its
    Components in South Chicago," Regional Science Association;
    Papers and Proceedings, XI (1964), 173-83; W.  Alonzo,  "A
    Theory of the Urban Land Market," Regional Science
    Association:  Papers and Proceedings, VI (1960), 149-57;
    L. Wingo, Transportation and Urban Land, (Washington:
    Resources for the Future, Inc., 1961).

2.  Ronald G. Ridker, The Economic Costs of Air Pollution:
    Studies in Measurement.  Praeger, 1967.

3.  Thomas Crocker and Robert Anderson, "Air Pollution and  Housing:
    Some Findings," Institute For Research in the Behavioral,
    Economic, and Management Sciences, No. 264 (January, 1970).

4.  J.F. Kain and J.M. Quigley, "Measuring the Value of Housing
    Quality," Journal of the American Statistical Association,
    LXV, (June, 1970), 532-48.

5.  R.F. Muth, Cities and Housing, (Chicago, University of
    Chicago Press, 1968).

6.  R.F. Muth, "The Variation of Population Density and Its
    Components in South Chicago," Regional Science Association;
    Papers and Proceedings. XI (1964), 173-83.

7.  U.S. National Center For Air Pollution Control, Cincinnati,
    "Air Quality Measurements," Interstate Air Pollution Study,
    Phase II Project Report iii (Washington:  Government Printing

-------
                          Appendix B


A COMMENT ON"PROPERTY VALUES AND AIR POLLUTION:  A CROSS SECTION

    ANALYSIS OF THE ST. LOUIS URBAN AREA*,' BY KENNETH WIEAND
                    Robert J. Anderson, Jr.
                      Purdue University

                      Thomao D. Crocker
             University of California Riverside
                              I.

    In accordance with principles of commentary reportedly

established by Mark Anthony, we come not to praise what is

praiseworthy in Wieand's paper, but rather to bury that which we

believe to be in error.  Ironically, we contend that Wieand's

dismissal on logical grounds of our results and those of other

investigators Is fundamentally illogical.

    In section II, Wieand's contention that we and others have used

a theoretically incorrect dependent variable in our empirical

work is evaluated.  Then, in section III, some results from past

property value studies not generally available are reported.  In

section IV, we present some new empirical evidence and offer some

concluding comments.

                              II.

    It is well-known that no universally accepted concept of a

commodity exists in economics.  Witness the economist's continuing

concern with aggregation problems.  To modify only slightly


-------
                               B-2



defined In accordance with the purposes of a theory.  The


fundamental difference between Wieand's work and that of previous


investigators lies in the adopted definition of commodity units.


Wieand treats "housing" as a single commodity, whereas other


investigators treat physically different properties as distinctly


different commodities.


     Following Muth (1969), Wieand defines observed "property
         s,

values" or rentals to be identically the product of two


unobservable magnitudes, the "price of housing services" and the


"quantity of housing services".  Under general assumptions, Wieand


demonstrates that if such a definition is adopted,  then it is the


case that property value  is neither equal to nor does it vary


with the "price of housing services".  This conclusion is


unimpeachable, as is the logic to which it gives rise in the search


for an observable proxy variable for the "price of  housing services".


     It does not follow, however, that property value is not a


measure of price under all definitions of commodity units and


attendant prices.  Yet Wieand's criticism of our work rests, insofar


as we are able to determine, on precisely this non-sequitur.  To


reject theorems based on one set of definitions and axioms because


they happen to differ from one's own theorems based on a different


set of definitions and axioms is at best unfair, and at worst bad


logic.



-------
                               B-3






work of previous investigators is Lancaster's (1966) formulation




of consumer behavior and Baumol and Quandt's (1966) empirical




work on the demand for abstract modes of transportation.  We




shall follow Lancaster.




     The point of departure of these approaches to demand theory




is that utility functions are defined not over traditionally




conceived goods but rather over characteristics embodied in goods.




The endowment of characteristics embodied in any good is presumed




to be objective in the sense that all consumers perceive identical




endowments in the same good.  The allocation problem of the consumer




is to consume that basket of goods which yields a mix and magnitude




of characteristics maximizing his utility subject to his budget




constraint.  Assuming that goods and characteristics are linearly




related (that the consumption technology is linear in Lancaster's




phrase), the problem of the consumer may be formulated




instructively as




     Maximize:    U(z)




     subject to:  p'x = y




                  z = Bx




                  z,x > 0




where z is an mxl vector of characteristics, p is an nxl vector of




good prices, y is a scalar representing disposable money income, and




B is an mxn matrix, the (i,j) element of which gives units of the ith





-------
                               B-4

     Consider the first order conditions of consumer equilibrium,

     (1)   U1 Vt z - Xp  = 0         i = 1, ..., n

           y - p'x = 0

where U1 is the transpose of  3 U/ 9 z, and where V ^z = 9 z/ J)x^.  In

the particular case of a linear consumption technology,  V z = b^ is

the ith column of the consumption technology matrix B.

     If the conditions of the implicit function theorem are

fulfilled by the implicitly defined vector function (1), there

exists a unique explicitly defined vector function

     (la)/ J\ = G(x, y)

The coordinate functions of G( ) which pertain to the price vectors

of p may be interpreted as offer functions, giving prices offered

for various quantities and income.  These functions may be easily

obtained directly from the first-order conditions, which by

rearrangement and substitution yield

                   y U1
     (lb.1)   Pi -5	
                   £ U1 V,zx,
                      y
     It is evident that the consumption technology is instrumental
in the determination of marginal rates of substitution among
commodities and hence Is instrumental in determining demands.  Note

-------
                               B-5




the characteristics which it yields.  That is, goods which yield


the same mix and magnitude of characteristics (goods for which the


V  . z are identical) are perfect substitutes, on a unit for unit


basis, and therefore bear the same price.


     Equation (lb.1) is the theoretical underpinning for the


statistical work with property values performed by us and others.


Treating the observed average characteristics of each census


tract as an observation on 7,z = b., and median property value as


an observation on p^, we have attempted to explain differences in

                        2
PI in tern's of y and b .   We thus treat each census tract


observation as though it were an observation on a different


commodity, while Wieand treats his observations as though they


pertain to the same commodity.


     Some results from past studies of air pollution and residential


property values are reported below in Table I.  All investigators


believe they have found statistically significant negative


relationships between air pollution and property values.  While


the specifications differ in some respects, the air pollution


results are remarkably uniform.  That is, several replications


have yielded very similar results, even though the structure of


residential property markets among cities may differ widely.  This


is cause to be cautiously confident that some misspecification


is not at base responsible for the observed negative relationship.



-------
                               B-6






investigators, precise comparisons are not possible.   Nevertheless,




estimates of marginal property value losses vary between roughly




$250 and $1000 per residential unit for ten to fifteen percent




increments in the mean value of the various pollution measures used.




Clearly these results and the conclusions which might be drawn from





-------
Dependent
                                                   TABLE I

             Some Results of Past Studies of Air Pollution and Residential Property Values


ndependent
CONSTANT
In PPT
In AMS
In ITL
In MRM
In PPU
In RMFI
In RHPM
In UKR
In JEW
In M)0
In MFI
In DIS
In OLD
In NWT
In DLP
2
R2
*•
S
F
Zerbe(1969V

In MPV
8.97

-0.1206
0 .0041
0.2570
0.1720
0.0001
-0.0001
0.0082
0.0043
0.0029






0.942
0.0846
107.83
r Zerbe(1969)^

In MPV
8.72

-0.0810

0.1260



0.00004*

0.0101
0.00004*





0.923
0.0488
72.55
Peckham(1970)

In MPV
4.7821
-0.1155
-0.0958

0.44973






0.4867
0.0575
-0.0415
-0.0054*
-0.0257

0.766

80.07
Anderson- +
Crocker(1970)
In MPV
-1.0705
-0.0627
-0.0412*

1.0996






0.7598
-0.0885*
-0.0036*
-0.0004*
-0.0267

0.877
0.0138

Anderson- +
Crocker(1970)
In MPV
-1.2325
-0.06M
-0.0649

0.8246






0.8130
0.0349*
-0.0464
-0.0133
-0.0028*

0.916
0.0114

Anderson- .
Crocker (1970)
In MPV
1.1617
-0.1698
0.0010*

0.9064






0.9970 ?
-0.0312 ^
-0.0213
0.0321
0.0113*

0.790
0.0179

  *Not  significantly different from zero at .05, 1 tailed test.


  ^Regression  included only observations on tracts where at least 75% of dwelling units were single
    family  residential  (generally suburban areas) .

  it

-------
                               B-8






                       NOTES TO TABLE I






PFT   annual arithmetic mean suspended participates




AMS   annual arithmetic mean sulfation




ITL   percentage Italian




MRM   median number of rooms



PPU   people per dwelling unit, average




RMFI  residualized median family income




RHPM  residualized housing units per mile




OKR   percentage Ukranian




JEW   percentage Jewish




MOO   neighborhood occupational homogeneity




MFI   median family income




DIS   distance to central business district




OLD   percentage of housing units more than 20 years old



NWT   percent nonwhite




DLP   percent housing units dilapidated






Regressions reported in columns of this table are based respectively




on data from Toronto (Ontario, Canada), Hamilton (Ontario, Canada),





-------
                               B-9



                               IV.


     If we may take it as established that the logical problem


Wieand claims to have demonstrated in previous work is really no


problem at all, it remains to determine the source of the


difference between his results and those of other investigators.


Although it is possible to entertain a near infinitude of dark


suspicions of misspecification and other errors in giving


empirical content to both theories, we believe that the divergence


of results is a matter of chance  pure and simple.  This conjecture


is based primarily on some regressions we have recently run using


better data than the Census material on which all earlier work


has been based.


     The results in Table 2 are based on FHA data for individual

                                             3
property transactions in the City of Chicago.   Air pollution


measures, which are interpolations from basic point measurements


made by the Chicago Air Pollution Control District, refer to the


mean annual suspended particulates and sulfur dioxide in the calendar


year immediately preceding the year of property sale.  As with our


earlier work with census tract data, we have included measures of


both suspended particulates and sulfur oxides in all equations


even though the two tend to be so collinear that it is difficult


to gauge the independent effect of each.  In column 1 of the


table, a specification analogous to that of Anderson and Crocker



-------
                               B-10






price at which the transaction occurred.  Column 2 reports the




results for a regression in which the natural log of the FHA




estimated price of the site for each transaction in the sample




is used as the dependent variable.  The results reported in




column 3, where the natural log of the ratio of sale price to lot




size is used as the dependent variable, were obtained using a




specification analogous toWieand's.




     Under each specification, the coefficient of at least one of




the pollution measures is significantly negative and the sum of the




coefficients is negative.  In forms not reported in Table 2




which employ only one pollution measure as an explanatory variable,




the coefficient of the included variable is always significantly




negative.  Evaluated at the means of the relevant variables, the




marginal capitalized damages in column 1 are $474.16 for each




additional ten  ug/M/day of suspended particulates plus an




additional one ppb per twenty-four hours of sulfur dioxide.  In




column 2, the analogous damages are $191.06.  A similar computation




for column 3 produces marginal capitalized damages of $.21 per




square foot of lot size.  This yields an average marginal




capitalized damage per residential property of $869.19, a figure




among the highest estimates obtained in all previous studies.




     Comparisons of Wieand's results for St. Louis with our own, and





-------
                               B-ll
                             TABLE 2
               Some New Results for Chicago - 1967
Constant
PRT66
SUL66
TCINC
LIVAR
HSAGE
MODUR
LOTSZ
SQIDX
INC ID
DISSM
DLAKE
INC66
FRAME
DTTYP
NHAGE
CRIMX
STDPER
WHITE
INDUT
CMMRC
R2
\ 1) *
In SALEP-
4.1532
-0.3998
0.0610*
0.3305
0.2356
-0.0465
0.4063
0.0917
-0.0729
0.0361
0.0321*
-0.0202
0.1216
-0.0810
0.1004

-0.0296




0.771
(2)
In SITEP
7.0780
-0.0005
0.0001*
0.0004



0.0002
-0.0543

0.0003*
-0.0024
0.00005


-0.0027

0.0056
0.0003*
-0.0041
-0.0013*
0.567
(3)
In SALEP
LOTSZ
2.6615
-0.0053
0.0012*
-0.00005*
-0.00004*
-0.0039
0.0011

-0.0138*

-0.0028
-0.0011*

-0.1070
-0.2906

-0.0262*
0.0009*
0.0017
-0.0059
0.0049
0.315
 S                   0.1126            0.1866            0.2455
 *Not significantly different from zero  at .05,  1  tailed  test.

-------
                                B-12


                         Notes to TABLE 2


PRT66 = annual arithmetic mean suspected particulates, 1966, in
        ui;/M3/ day.

SUL66 = annual arithmetic mean sulfur dioxide in ppm by volume per
        twenty-four hours.

TCINC = total current income of family in dollars.

LIVAR = living area of house in square feet.

HSAGE - age of house in years.

MODUR = mortgage duration in years.

LOTSZ = lot size in square feet.

SQIDX = school quality index 1 » highest, 4 = lowest.

INC ID = incidental expenses associated with house in dollars.

DISSM = distance to the intersection of State and Madison in tenths
        of miles.

DLAKE = distance to lake in tenths of miles.

INC66 = median family income in community area, 1966, in dollars.

FRAME = dummy for house type.

DTTYP = dummy for detached.

CRIMX = neighborhood crime rate, an index where the base is the
        arithmetic mean rate for the City of Chicago.

STDPER= percent standard.

WHITE = percent white.

INPUT = industrial land within one square mile in hundredths of
        square miles.

CMMRC = commercial land within one square mile in hundredths of
        square miles .

SALEP = sale price .


-------
                               B-13






suggest that Wieand, in general, explains a smaller proportion




of the variation in his dependent variable than we explain in the




dependent variable we adopt.  That is Wieand's specification




apparently involves a substantially higher "noise-to-signal ratio"




than does that under which we proceed.  Other things being




equal, one would suppose that it is harder under Wieand's




specification than it is under ours to distinguish the relatively




minor influence of air pollution on property values from other





-------
                               B-14
                            FOOTNOTES
1.   We assume that the non-negative constraints are not binding.

2.   Under common restrictions on U(«)» X is a function of y alone.
     given p.

3.   The research for these results was  supported by Research
     Contract CFA 22-69-52 of the National Air Pollution Central

-------
                               B-15


                          BIBLIOGRAPHY
1.   Anderson, R.J., Jr., and T.C.  Crocker,  Air Pollution and
     Housing:  Some Findings. Paper No.  264, Institute for Research
     In the Behavioral, Economic, and Management Sciences, (Jan.  1970).

2.   Lancaster, K.J., "A New Approach to Consumer Theory," J.
     of Political Economy, 74 (April 1966),  132-157.

3.   Muth, R.F., Cities and Housing, Chicago:   Univ.  of Chicago
     Press (1969).

4.   Quandt, R.E., and W.J. Baumol, "The Demand for Abstract Transport
     Modes:  Theory and Measurement," J. of  Regional  Science,
     6 (Winter, 1966), 432-441.

5.   Peckham, B.W., Private communication dated May 13, 1970.

6.   Zerbe, R.O., Jr., The Economics of  Air  Pollution:   A Cost
     Benefit Approach. Toronto:  Ontario Dept.  of Public Health

-------