United States Environmental Protection Agency Air And Radiation (ANR-459) EPA 520/1-90-006 juiy 1990 The Cost Of Implementing Protective Action Guides For Food ------- Cost of Implementing Protective Action Guides for Food Dr. Byron Hunger Office of Radiation Programs U.S. Environmental Protection Agency Washington, DC July 1990 Printed on Recycled Paper ------- CONTENTS TABLES FIGURES CONTENTS 1. Introduction 1.1 General Descrip~ion of Methodology 1.2 Selection of Foods for Study Measurement of the Economic Effects of PAGs 2. 2.2 2.1 Methodology 2.3 Results Data 2.3.1 Wheat 2.3.2 Tomatoes 2.3.3 Soybeans 2.3.4 Snapbeans 2.3.5 Milk 2.3.6 Lettuce 2.3.7 Eggs 2.3.8 Chicken 2.3.9 Beef 2.3.10 Sweet Corn 2.3.11 Oranges ii! Paae . iii v vii 1 2 6 7 . 10 10 11 11 16 20 20 20 31 31 31 31 44 44 ------- COHTERTS (CoD~iDUed) Paae 3. Analogous Events . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51 3.1 The Experience with Soybeans . . . . . . . . . . . . 51 3.2 The Experience with Wheat . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51 REFERENCES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53 iv ------- LIST OF TABLES No. 1 Prices and Quantities of Farm Commodities, 2 Average for 1983-5, by u.s. and Leading State Farm Level Own Price Elasticities of Demand . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3 Summary of Total, National Welfare Losses by Crop Welfare Losses Due to Removal of Wheat from Market . . . . . . . 4 5 6 Worksheet on Wheat . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Welfare Losses due to Removal of Tomatoes from Market 7 8 Worksheet on Tomatoes . . . . . ............. Welfare Losses Due to Removal of Soybeans from Market Worksheet on Soybeans 9 . . . . . . . . . . ........ 10 Welfare Losses Due to Removal of Snapbeans from Market 11 Worksheet on Snapbeans . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12 Welfare Losses Due to Removal of Milk from Market . . . . 13 Worksheet on Milk ....... . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14 Welfare Losses Due to Removal of Lettuce from Market 15 Worksheet on Lettuce . . . . . . . . . ......... 16 Welfare Losses Due to Removal of Eggs from Market 17 Worksheet on Eggs . . . . ....... . . . . ......... 18 Welfare Losses Due to Removal of Chicken from Market 19 Worksheet on Chicken . . . . . . . . . ......... 20 Welfare Losses Due to Removal of Beef from Market 21 Worksheet on Beef . . . . ....... ............. v ~ 3 3 8 12 14 17 19 21 23 25 27 37 30 32 34 35 37 38 40 41 43 ------- LIS~ or ~ABLBS (Continued) No. 22 Welfare Losses Due to Removal of Sweet Corn from Market 23 Worksheet on Sweet Corn . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24 Welfare Losses Due to Removal of Oranges from Market 25 Worksheet on Oranges . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . vi ~ 45 47 . . 48 50 ------- LIST OF FIGURES 80. 1 2 Linear Demand Curve ....... . . . . . . . . . . . Commodities Ranked by Welfare Loss . . . . . . . . . . . 3 4 Welfare Losses Due to Removal of Wheat . . . . . . . . . Timing and Expenditures for Wheat Losses Due to Removal of Tomatoes . . . . . . . . . . . . 5 6 . . . . . . . . . . . . Losses Due to Removal of Soybeans . . . . . . . . . . . . 7 8 Timing of Expenditures for Soybeans . . . . . . . . . . . Losses Due to Removal of Snapbeans Losses Due to Removal of Milk . . . . . . . . . . . 9 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10 Losses Due to Removal of Lettuce . . . . . . . . . . . . 11 Losses Due to Removal of Eggs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12 Losses Due to Removal of Chicken . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 Losses Due to Removal of Beef . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14 Losses Due to Removal of Sweet Corn . . . . . . . . . . . 15 Losses Due to Removal of Oranges . . . . . . . . . . . . vii Page . . 4 8 13 15 18 22 24 26 29 33 36 39 42 46 49 ------- 1. IH~RODUC~IOH Protective Action Guides (PAGs) provide direction to public and private sector officials to aid them in making decisions to protect the public in case of accidents that release radiation or radioactive materials to the environment. Expressed in terms of projected radiation dose, PAGs may address a variety of protec- tive actions to be taken after such an event. The protective action being considered in this analysis is the withdrawal of food from public consumption. There are three stages in establishing the dose level for inges- tion PAGs. The first stage is to determine the dose level that would satisfy basic health criteria. Foods that would cause a dose equal to or higher than this level would be unacceptable for use. The second stage is to examine the economic costs and benefits of the removal of foods that would cause a lower dose than meet health criteria to determine if there is net benefit for a more stringent standard of removal. Additional food that would cause an exposure whose value is judged to be equal to or greater than the level at which the incremental costs equal the incremental benefits would be withdrawn from consumption if the associated exposures were smaller than those established on purely health grounds. A third stage would consider the level at which withdrawal of contaminated food would incur health prob- lems. This report addresses the second of these stages. To aid in establishing the radiation dose at which cost may serve as a basis for removal of food from markets, this study develops estimates of the cost society would bear if food that had reached various stages in the farming to retail sale chain were removed from production or sales. No attempt is made in this report to establish PAG values. The study approaches cost issues in two ways. First, it measures the sum of consumer and producer surpluses associated with withdrawals of some key foods in significant quantities, based on the own-price elasticity of demand -- defined as the percent change in the quantity of a good demanded due to a one percent increase in its own price -- for the farm product and the variable costs sunk into production at various stages. Second, it examines the effects of major analo- gous events such as the drought which claimed fourteen percent and 20 percent respectively of the u.S. wheat and soybean har- vests in 1988. By integrating these two approaches, an understanding of the nature and magnitudes of the economic effects associated with implementing protective action for food is reached. These approaches are applied to 11 agricultural products representing the major categories of food types -- wheat, tomatoes soybeans snapbeans, milk, lettuce, eggs, chicken, beef, sweet c~rn, and' 1 ------- oranges. The analyses measure the overall costs to society and how the costs are distributed among affected farmers, other farmers growing the same crop but out of the area ~pacted, and consumers in the United States. 1.1 GENERAL DESCRIPTION OF METHODOLOGY The method for measuring changes in economic welfare -- i.e., changes in social costs or social benefits -- used in this study is to measure changes in consumer and producer surpluses based on specific assumptions and data. This approach is both conceptual- ly sound and practical to implement.' The study assumes a lin- ear demand curve for each farm product established by using recent prices and quantities as reported by the U.S. Department of Agriculture and "own-price elasticities of demand" for the product. The maximum size of product removals were based on the amount of the product grown in the state that produces the most of that product. These data are shown in Tables 1 and 2. The demand curve for the individual farm products is critical to measurement of both consumer and producer surplus. A reduction in the quantity of a product placed on the market leads to a higher price, other things constant. The size of the price hike depends on the nature of the demand curve. For producers, the change of total revenue depends on the quantity demanded and on the slope of the demand curve at the initial price-output combi- nation. Figure 1 depicts the linear demand curve HK for wheat based on data in Tables 1 and 2. Supply 1 is the initial supply curve and Supply 2 is the supply curve when all the wheat pro- duced in Kansas is removed from market. Assumptions regarding the supply curves are discussed below. Point C is the initial price-quantity combination. The price of wheat increases by FE as supply decreases by BA. Consumer surplus is the area below the demand curve and above the equilibrium price. Producer surplus is the area above the supply curve and below the equilibrium price. On Figure 1, the initial consumer surplus is the area HCE and the initial producer surplus is the area ECBO. A decrease in supply from Supply 1 to Supply 2 increases the price from OE to OF, reduces consumer surplus to HGF -- which is clearly smaller -- and changes producer surplus to FGAO -- which may be smaller or larger than before, but in this case is larger. The sign of changes in producer surplus will be discussed in more detail below. The loss of consumer surplus is depicted by the trapezoid FECG which is composed of the rectangle FEDG and the triangle GDC. The gain in producer surplus in this example is FOAG - EOBC. Because EOAD is common 'William Baumol, Economic Theorv and Ooerations Analvsis 4th ed. (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, 1977), pp. 497-500. 2 ------- Table 1: Prices and quantities of far. c088Odities, avera~es for 1983-5, by u.s. and leading state United States State With Highest Output --------------------------- --------------------------------------------------- Unit of Percent of COIIIIIOdity Measure Price Quantity Name of State Price Quantity US Output ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------ WHEAT BUSHELS S3.36 2,479,788,667 KANSAS S3.28 437,533,333 17.6 TOMATOES CWT S24.63 28,399,667 FLORIDA S27. 73 13,893,333 48.9 SOYBEANS BUSHELS S6.25 1,865,055,333 ILLINOIS S6.38 311,201,667 16.7 SNAPBEANS TONS S166.67 652,003 WISCONSIN S148.00 231,543 35.5 "ILK * POUNDS SO.13 139,937,000,000 WISCONSIN SO.12 24,620,000,000 17.6 LETTUCE CWT S11.4O 61,343,667 CALIFORNIA S11 .30 43,961,667 71.7 EGGS * DOZEN SO.65 5,693,208,333 CALIFORNIA SO. 50 682,375,000 12.0 CHICKEN * POUNDS SO.32 18,356,867,000 ARKANSAS SO.34 3,007,852,000 16.4 BEEF * POUNDS SO.73 39,946,992,000 TEXAS SO.78 5,320,460,000 13.3 SWEET CORN CWT S12.77 15,407,667 FLORIDA S13.57 4,703,000 30.5 ORANGES BOXES S7.77 184,346,667 FLORIDA S8.07 120,066,667 65.1 * data not available for all three years Source: USDA, AGRICULTURAL STATISTICS 1986 Table 2: Farm level own price elasticities of demand Source and Value Commodity George & King -------------------------------------------------------------- ID of Other Other --------------------------------------------------------------------------- WHEAT TOHATOES SOYBEANS SNAPBEANS HILK LETTUCE EGGS CHICKEN BEEF SWEET CORN -0.244 -0.355 -0.234 -0.32 -0.095 -0.225 -0.602 -0.416 ORANGES -0.455 --------------------------------------------------------------------------- 3 -0.2 DOA ERS -0.79 Hertel & Tsigas "Oilseeds" -0.513 Hertel & Tsigas "Dai ry" -0.407 -0.320 Hertel & Tsigas "Red Heats" George & King, RETAIL "Other Fresh Vegitables" ------- Figure 1. Linear Demand Curve Price per Bushel $20 $15 $10 ~ Supply 2 Suppl 1 F $5 E D o A. $0 o 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 Bushels of Wheat (Millions) 3000 K 3500 ------- to both areas, the difference is FEDG - DABC. The combined reduction in consumer and producer surplus is therefore equal to FEDG - GDC + FEDG - DABC, or - GDC - DABC because FEDG is in both measures with opposite sign. Each of these areas has significance to the analysis of the cost of withdrawing food from use. GDC is the "deadweight loss" of consumer surplus; DABC is the loss of revenues to the Kansas farmers whose wheat is kept from market; and FEDG is the increase in revenues enjoyed by all other wheat farmers and at the same time the additional expenditures made by consumers for the remaining wheat. Before the decrease in supply FEDG was part of consumer surplus, afterwards it is part of producer surplus. This transfer of wealth is a major distributional aspect of any reduction in supply. Demand for nearly all agricultural products has been measured to be "inelastic" in most studies performed to date. This means that consumers make relatively small adjustments in purchases in response to changes in price. Therefore, and of interest in this study, consumers respond to a reduction in the quantity available by bidding up the price by a relatively large amount compared to the size of the reduction. This leads to a seemingly perverse result: when the quantity of farm products allowed to go to market is reduced, the total revenue collected by all farmers increases. However this gain is collected by farmers other than the ones whose crops were removed from market. The affected farmers' revenues fall to zero. FEDG measures the gain experi- enced by other wheat farmers and DABC the loss borne by affected wheat farmers. FEDG will exceed DABC when demand is inelastic, so the change in producer surplus is positive when demand is inelastic and negative when demand is elastic. Market behavior is analyzed by investigating the interaction of the demand and supply curves. Therefore it is also necessary to make explicit the assumptions regarding the supply curve on which the study is based. The major assumption regarding the supply curve is that supply of the harvest of an agricultural crop is fixed once planting decisions are made, except for random factors such as weather. This is characterized as a vertical supply curve. When the harvest is reduced due to a PAG, the vertical supply curve is shifted to the left by a corresponding amount. Given these assumptions the area under the demand curve and between the two vertical supply curves -- Supply 1 and Supply 2 -- is the total welfare loss due to the withdrawal of food from use. These quantities are measured for each of the 11 farm products studied in the following chapter. The major distribu- tional effects of withdrawing crops from market include the two components of welfare loss -- the deadweight loss of consumer surplus and the loss of revenues by affected farmers -- as well as the large transfer of money from consumers to farmers. The 5 ------- latter quantity is not part of the overall welfare loss attribut- able to the protective action; rather it is a transfer from consumers surplus to producer surplus, shown in Figure 1 as FEDG. Thus the distributional effects -- large losses by consumers including both the deadweight loss and increased expenditure on the remaining crop, large gains by farmers other than those directly affected by the protective action, and complete losses by farmers directly affected by the protective action -- must be considered as well as the net overall welfare effect. 1.2 SELECTION OF FOODS FOR STUDY Food products were selected from major categories of foods as delineated by the u.s. Department of Agriculture. These catego- ries are: 1) grains, from which wheat was selected; 2) cotton, tobacco, sugar crops, and honey; 3) oilseeds, fats, and oils, which is represented in the study by soybeans; 4) vegetables and melons, represented by lettuce, tomatoes, snapbeans and sweet corn; 5) fruits, tree nuts, and horticultural specialties, represented by oranges; 6) hay, seeds and minor field crops; 7) cattle, hogs and sheep, represented by beef; and 8) dairy and poultry products, represented by milk, eggs, and chicken. The selection is intended to identify farm products that are widely used and for which good data are available. 6 ------- 2. MEASUREMENT OF ~BE ECONOMIC EFFEC~S OF PRO~EC~IVE AC~ION The method used in this study, discussed in more detail below, measures the losses to consumers and producers in dollars. Figure 2 and Table 3 show the results for 100 percent losses of the output of the states that produce the most of the commodity in question. The welfare losses to society for the commodities studied range from $4.4 billion for beef to $1 hundred million for snapbeans and sweet corn. Smaller increments of loss were also calculated and are given in Section 2.3 below. Before discussing these results, more detail is provided regarding methodology and data. 2.1 ME~BODOLOGY Measuring changes in consumer and producer surpluses is a widely accepted operational method of evaluating welfare losses due to changes in the price or availability of a product. There are both theoretical and practical considerations in the application of this technique. One theoretical issue in the measurement of consumer surplus concerns the implicit change of the consumer's income as the price of the commodity is changed. Although very interesting conceptually, this issue leads to only very small differences in the measurement of consumer surplus. Implicit changes in consumer income are ignored here. A second theoreti- cal issue that is less easily ignored is the question of whether to approach the measurement of consumer and producer surplus in a partial or a general equilibrium framework. The partial equilib- rium framework assumes that the prices of other goods and servic- es remain constant even though there is a second order shift in the demand for them. General equilibrium analysis is more complex because the effects of the initial shift must be traced through the entire economy. Several recent articles have used the general equilibrium ap- proach in measuring the own-price elasticities of demand -- defined above -- and the cross-price elasticities of demand -- defined as the percent change in the demand for a good due to a one percent change in the price of another good -- for groupings 7 ------- Figure 2. Commodities Ranked by Welfare Loss WILrAIU LOSS 1$1 IBlIl1o..1 7 2 6 5 6 3 , 5 , 3 1 11 8 COMMODITY ROMBBK 2 7 10 , Table 3: Summary of total, national welfare losses by crop Conunodity Conunodity Number Total Welfare Loss Nationwide ---------------------------------------------------------- BEEF MILK LETTUCE SOYBEANS WHEAT ORANGES CHICKEN TOMATOES EGGS SWEET CORN SNAP BEANS 9 5 6 3 1 11 8 2 7 10 4 $6,250,279,173 $4,001,976,386 $2,391,459,007 $2,150,417,321 $1,999,655,380 $1,601,316,769 $1,093,502,554 $578,050,352 $561,762,037 $88,677,520 $67,873,695 8 ------- of agricultural products.2 These studies simultaneously measure a set of own-price and cross-price elasticities in a theoretical- ly correct way, but have been applied to product groups rather than individual products. A third theoretical issue is the shape of the demand curve. Closely related to this issue is the question, for how large a perturbation can the elasticity be expected to hold? Two speci- fications of the demand curves that can be derived using the available data are constant elasticity demand curves and linear demand curves. As their name suggests, constant elasticity demand curves have the same elasticity at all points on the demand curve. As the quantity demanded gets smaller, the down- ward slope of these curves gets steeper. On the other hand, linear demand curves have constant slope, but the own-price elasticity of demand is different at each point on the curve. Regardless of the nature of the curve, it must be assumed that the elasticity of the curve holds only in the neighborhood of the mean of the data used in estimating the curve. Whether the size of changes in supplies of agricultural products used in this study is too large to be considered to be in this neighborhood is an open question. However, the information presented in Section 3 of this study suggests that the perturbations used in this study are within the range of common experience. The smaller perturbations calculated, such as 10 or 20 percent of the whole product of the leading state, rather than 100 percent, are likely to result in more accurate measures of welfare loss. Linear demand curves are used in this study. As indicated in graphs and tables in Section 2.3, there is one component of the welfare measure that is quite reliably measured and does not depend on the technical theoretical issues raised above. DABC in Figure 1 is an important component of welfare loss and is easily and accurately measured. It is the amount of product taken off the market times the market price that would have been in effect if the product had not been removed from market. In some cases it constitutes a very large part of the welfare loss. In all cases it is the lower limit to an estima- 2Thomas W. Hertel and Marinos E. Tsigas, "General Equilibri- um Analysis of Supply Control in u.S. Agriculture," Purdue University, April 1989. Thomas W. Hertel et. al., "Competing Farm Level General Equilibrium Demand Elasticities for Agricultural Commodities," Research Bulletin No. 988 of the Agricultural Experiment Station, Purdue University, W. Lafayette, Indiana. Michael K. Wohlgenant, "Demand for Farm Output in a Complete System of Demand Functions," American Journal of Aaricultural Economics, May 1989, pp. 241-252. 9 ------- tion of the loss. In Section 2.3, the size of the loss attribut- able to DABC in Figure 1 is compared to the loss attributable to GDC, the deadweight loss of consumer surplus. Costs of production are also a factor in estimating the welfare losses due to the withdrawal of food from use. The timing of the protective action, that is, during what part of the year the nuclear event occurs that necessitates its application, deter- mines the amount of variable costs that would have been saved by withholding variable resources after the protective action has been implemented. At one extreme, if the protective actions were applied after harvest is completed and the product stored safely, but before expenditures on seeds and other variable inputs for the next planting were made, the welfare losses borne by farmers would be reduced by the savings on these items. At the other extreme, if the protective action were applied to products just harvested, all the variable cost of production for that agricul- tural product would have been spent, and no savings would be possible. Because the normal state of affairs is for farmers to plant and harvest, and spend the associated amounts on variable inputs, and because the welfare losses being measured in this study are changes from the status quo, the welfare losses discussed above assume the second extreme case. Therefore any differences between the maximum expenditure on variable costs and the amount actually spent should be subtracted from the amounts estimated. Another way of putting it is that the welfare losses measured under the demand curve in Figure 1 are worst case losses. The information needed to estimate variable cost by time are avail- able for wheat and soybeans. The matter is discussed in more detail in Sections 2.3.1 and 2.3.3. 2.2 DATA Two types of data are required for this studya 1) Relatively unprocessed data regarding price, quantity, dates of planting, and production costs for various agricultural products and 2) highly processed data in the form of price elasticities of demand. With regard to the first tyPe of data, the u.S. Depart- ment of Agriculture's book Agricultural statistics, 1986, their handbook Usual Planting and Harvesting Dates for U.s. Pield Crops, (USDA SRS Agricultural Handbook 628, April 1984), and their report Economic Indicators of the Parm Sector Costs of Production, 1987, (USDA ERS) provided the needed information. Elasticities of demand are not so easily found. In 1971 P. S. George and G. A. King published a matrix of farm level own-price elasticities and cross-price elasticities for 49 agricultural products. This is the most complete set of farm level elasticities ever published. However, current researchers have two critiques of this data. The first is that the George 10 ------- and King elasticities are dated because they are based on consum- er tastes, income and prices and the population size of the 1950's and 1960's. The second is that the techniques George and King used in deriving farm level elasticities of demand from retail level elasticities of demand are based on fixed linear production functions that do not allow for substitutions due to changing prices. These researchers, for example Wohlgenant and Hertel who were referenced above, have developed a more flexible theoretical approach in the form of computable general equilibri- um models and various econometric techniques that allow theoreti- cally correct measurements of elasticities to be made. But unfortunately, these techniques are expensive to use in that they require large amounts of data. Therefore the results that have been presented to date are for small numbers of highly aggregated groups of agricultural products. In this study, the George and King farm price elasticities are used except as otherwise noted in Table 2. The following sections apply the data to the 11 individual agricultural products that are the subject of this study. 2.3 RESULTS 2.3.1 Wheat Table 4 and Figure 3 show the loss of farm revenue by farmers affected by withdrawal of food from use for 1 year, dead weight welfare loss, and total welfare loss nationwide if all the wheat in Kansas had to be removed from market immediately after har- vest. The prices and quantities used in these calculations are shown in Table 5, as u.s. price and production for 1983 through 1985. Wheat averaged $3.36 per bushel nationwide. During these years, Kansas grew 18 percent of the wheat produced in the United States of 0.4 billion of the 2.5 billion bushels produced. The loss of farm revenues to affected farmers in the event of withdrawal of 100 percent of Kansas wheat would be $1.5 billion, the dead weight welfare loss of $0.5 billion is 27 percent of the nearly $2 billion total welfare loss nationwide. As shown in Table 5, almost $5 billion would be transferred from consumers to the rest of u.s. farmers outside the affected region. Figure 3 and Table 4 show that smaller reductions in wheat coming to market result in dead weight losses that are smaller relative to total welfare losses than the dead weight losses due to larger removals. For example a 100 percent removal results in a dead weight loss equal to 26.6 percent of total welfare loss while a removal of 20 percent results in a dead weight loss equal to only 6.7 percent of total welfare loss. Two issues concerning the timing and magnitude of variable costs affect the cost of withdrawal of food from use. Figure 4a shows the timing of cumulative, total, variable, cash expenses (re 11 ------- Table 4: Welfare lossas due to removal of wheat from market Farm Level OWn Price Elasticity 01 Demand: -0.244 Amount of Commodity Removed -------..---.-.----------------- Percent of Loss of Farm Dead weight Total Deed Weight Largest Revenue in Welfare Welfare i.oss asa State Affected Area Loss Nationwide Percent of Production in Units Uni ts (in $) (in $) (in $) Tota l Loss ---------------------------------------------------.-.-------------------------------_._._--_._._------------- 100" 437,533,333 bushels 1,468,653,556 531,001,825 1,999,655,380 26.6" 90>: 393,780,000 bushels 1,321,788,200 430,111,478 1,751,899,678 24.6% 80" 350,026,667 bushels 1,174,922,844 339,841,168 1,514,764,012 22.4% 70" 306,273,333 bushels 1,0~8,057,489 260,190,894 1,288,248,383 20.2% 60" 262,520,000 bushels 881,192,133 191,160,657 1,072,352,790 17.8% 50% 218,766,667 bushels 734,326,778 132,750,456 867,077,234 15.3% 40X 175,013,333 bushels 587,461,422 84,960,292 672,421,714 12.6% .... 30r. 131,260,000 bushels 440,596,067 47,790,164 488,386,231 9.8% IV 20% 87,506,667 bushels 293,730,711 21,240,073 314,970,784 6.7X 1 Or. 43,753,333 bushels 146,865,356 5,310,018 152,175,374 3.5% ------- Figure 3. Welfare Losses Due to Removal of Wheat $ (Millions) 2500 2000 1500 1000 ..... w 500 o o 100 200 300 400 BUSHELS OF WHEAT REMOVED (Millions) -- TOTAL WELFARE LOSS -*- DEADWEIGHT LOSS -+- LOSS OF REVENUES 500 ------- T.ble 5: Uorksheet on whe.t INITIAL PRICE: INITIAL QUANTITY: INITIAL REVENUE: FARft LEVEL PRICE ELASTICITY OF DE"AND: $3.36 2,419,788,667 BUSHELS 18,323,823,958 -0.244 CHANGE IN QUANTITY: -18% (437, 533,333)BUSHELS CHANGE IN PRICE: HE" PRICE: PERCENT CHANGE IN PRICE: CHANGE IN TOTAL REVENUE TO ALL FARftERS: $2.43 $5.78 72% $3,488,414,744 LOSS OF REVENUES TO FLORIDA: GAIN TO REST OF NATION'S TOftATO FAR"ERS: ($1,468,653,556) $4,957,068,300 --- --------- ---- -------------------- - -------------------- PRODUCTION (in bushels) YEAR 1983 1984 1985 "EAN ------------------------------------------------------------------ KANSAS 448,200,000 431,200,000 433,200,000 437,533,333 U.S. 2,419,824,000 2,594,777,000 2,424,765,000 2,419,788,667 = - - - PRICE ($ per bushel> YEAR 1983 1984 1985 "EAN ------------------------------------------------------------------ KANSAS U.S. $3.46 $3.53 $3.32 $3.38 $3.05 $3.16 $3.28 $3.36 = - -==--==------------================= 14 ------- Figure 4. Timing and Bxpenditure for Wheat A. Tlmlnt of Cumulative Expenditure. for Spring and. Wintel wheaL . 1111111..., 1500 1000 3000 :as 0 0 2000 1500 500 o K A K J ~ A . 0 R D J r K ~ K J J A 8 Q B D ~ J 11081'8 ~ WIBTJlK - SPIUIlG B. Tlmlnt of Cumulative Expenditures of XaDlas WinLer WheaL . 1IIIIIIoui 800 700 300 tOO 500 400 :200 100 o K A K J J A 8 Q R D J , K ~ K J ~ A 8 Q 11 D J J M08T. ~ HORTH 15 ------- ferred to here as variable costs) sunk in production of spring and winter wheat. The values shown on Figure 4a are for the nation as a whole. Using Figure 4a, it can be seen how U.S. farmers would adjust their planting schedules in response to a decision to withdraw food from use. For example, should a decision affecting Kansas winter wheat -- Kansas only grows winter wheat -- occur in September 1990, after all winter wheat had been planted, the first adjustment in planting would be for the spring wheat crop in March 1991 and the first harvest re- flecting these adjustments would occur in August or September 1991. Referring to Figure 4b, which shows the timing of variable costs of Kansas winter wheat, it can be seen that only 17 percent of variable costs would have been spent by the beginning of Septem- ber, but 56 percent would have been spent by the beginning of October.Referring to the savings that Kansas farmers could realize if the decision for protective action occur early enough in the season, Figure 4b shows that variable costs Kansas wheat farmers could avoid would total $681 million. This entire amount would be saved if the decision were made in early July, after the previous harvest was safely in and before fertilizer and seeds have been applied for the next crop. This saving is about 46 percent of the total revenue Kansas farmers realize from their wheat. If the protective action is applied to harvested wheat none of the variable cost can be recovered. Fixed costs could not be recovered, unless the fields could be used for another activity that was not as sensitive to radioactivity as wheat. The savings in variable costs are subtracted from total welfare loss. For example, if 100 percent of Kansas wheat producers were advised to not plant a crop, $681 million would be subtracted from the nearly $2 billion welfare loss that was listed in Table 4. 2.3.2 Tomatoes Table 6, Figure 5, and Table 7 depict the results obtained for tomatoes. Forty-nine percent of the U.S. tomato crop is grown in Florida -- an average of 14 million cwt. of the just over 28 million cwt. grown nationwide. Deadweight loss would be 41 percent of total welfare loss nationwide -- $0.24 billion of $0.58 billion. With respect to distributional effects, the gain to non-affected farmers at the expense of consumers -- $0.49 billion -- is over 1.4 times the $0.34 billion loss borne by affected farmers. At low levels -- 10 percent of the Florida crop -- a smaller 6.4 percent of the total welfare loss is dead weight loss. Dead weight loss is lost to all of society. It is also more subject to error in calculations than loss of farm revenues -- so at these lower level, the total welfare loss is less subject to 16 ------- Table 6: Welfare losses due to removal of tomatoes from market Farm Level Own Price Elasticity of Demand: -0.355 Amount of Commodity Removed -------------------------------- Percent of Loss of Farm Dead Weight Tota l Dead Weight Largest Revenue in Welfare Welfare Loss 85a State Affected Area Loss Nationwide Percent of Production in Units Units (in $) (in $) (in $) Total Loss -----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------.......-.-------.- 1001. 13,893,333 cwt 342,239,111 235,811,241 578,050,352 4O.8X 901. 12,504,000 cwt 308,015,200 191,007,105 499,022,305 38.3:< 801. 11,114,667 cwt 273,791,289 150,919,194 424,710,483 35.5X 701. 9,725,333 cwt 239,567,378 115,547,508 355,114,886 32.5" 601. 8,336,000 cwt 205,343,467 84,892,047 290,235,513 29.2" 501. 6,946,667 cwt 171,119,556 58,952,810 230,072,366 25.6" 40Y. 5,557,333 cwt 136,895,644 37,729,799 174,625,443 21.6:< 301. 4,168,000 cwt 102,671,733 21,223,012 123,894,745 17.1" .... 201. 2,778,667 cwt 68,447,822 9,432,450 77,880,272 12.1" ....:J 101. 1,389,333 cwt 34,223,911 2,358,112 36,582,024 6.4" ------- $ (Millions) 600 500 400 300 200 .... Q) 100 0 0 2 Figure 5: Losses Due to Removal of Tomatoes 4 6 8 10 12 CWT. OF TOMATOES REMOVED (Millions) 14 16 --+- LOSS OF REVENU ES - TOTAL WELFARE LOSS -+- DEADWEIGHT LOSS ------- Table 7: I.Iorksheet on tocaatoes INITIAL PRICE: INITIAL QUANTITY: INITIAL REVENUE: FAR" LEVEL PRICE ELASTICITY OF DE"AND: CHANGE IN QUANTITY: CHANGE IN PRICE: NEW PRICE: PERCENT CHANGE IN PRICE: CHANGE IN TOTAL REVENUE TO ALL FARMERS: LOSS OF REVENUES TO FLORIDA: GAIN TO REST OF NATION'S TOMATO FARMERS: PRODUCTION (in cwt> YEAR 1983 $24.63 /CWT 28,399,667 CWT $699,578,456 -0.355 (G&K, -49% (13,893,333)CWT $33.95 /CWT $58.58 /CWT 138% $150,192,241 ($342,239,111) $492,431,353 pp. 64-5.) ------------------------------------- ----- -------- 1984 1985 ------------------------------------------------------------------ MEAN FLORIDA U.S. 13,664,000 27,237,000 ------------------------ --------------------------- 13,886,000 28,189,000 14,130,000 29,773,000 13,893,333 28,399,667 ----------------------------------------- PRICE ($ per cwt) YEAR 1983 1984 1985 ------------------------------------------------------------------ MEAN FLORIDA U.S. $27.60 $24.10 $26.60 $25.60 $29.00 $24.20 $27.73 $24.63 ===--================-----------------------------==--=====--======================= 19 ------- errors based on violations of assumptions regarding elasticities and shapes of demand curves. 2.3.3 Sovbean8 Table 8, Figure 6, and Table 9 provide the results for soybeans. Soybeans have a small deadweight loss -- less than 10 percent of total welfare loss -- even if 100 percent of the soybeans in Illinois were withdrawn from use. This is due to a relatively "high" elasticity of -0.79. Soybeans are not very inelastic. The total welfare loss due to loss of 100 percent of Illinois soybeans is $2.2 billion. Cumulative cost data, depicted in Figure 7 is available for soybeans grown in Illinois. One crop per year is planted around April and harvested by October. The $668 million expenditure in Illinois is 17 percent of the total national cash expenditure on variable costs of growing soybeans. As shown in Table 8, a total welfare loss of $2.2 billion would occur if a protective action decision affected 100 percent of an Illinois harvest of soybeans. If the decisions were made between November and March, the total welfare loss would be reduced by $668 million to $1.5 billion. Figure 7 can also show how much the savings would be if the action occurred during the growing season. For example, if it were initiated at the end of July $379 million of variable costs, or about 57 percent, could be avoided. 2.3.4 SnaDbean8 Table 10, Figure 8, and Table 11 provide the results for snap- beans. Thirty-six percent of u.S. snapbeans are grown in Wiscon- sin -- 232,000 tons compared to 652,000 tons. Demand for them is relatively inelastic at -0.234. Table 10 and Figure 8 show that total welfare loss due to a withdrawal of 100 percent of Wiscon- sin's snapbeans would be $68 million. Distributionally, other farmers would gain $106 million at consumer expense, dead weight losses would total $29 million, and loss of revenue by farmers directly affected by the withdrawal would be $39 million. 2.3.5 Milk Table 12, Figure 9, and Table 13 depict milk. If all the milk produced in a year in Wisconsin were removed from market, the total welfare loss would be $4 billion. Affected farmers would loose $3.1 billion of this and consumers would loose an addition- al deadweight loss of $0.9 billion -- 22 percent of the total. Approximately $8 billion would be lost to non-affected farmers by consumers due to a 55 percent increase in the price of milk. 20 ------- Table 8: Welfare losses due to removal of soybeans from market Farm Level Own Price Elasticity of Demand: -0.79 Amount 01 Commodity Removed ----------.--------------------- Percent of Loss of Farm Dead Weight Tota l Dead Weight Largest Revenue in Welfare Welfare Loss asa State Affected Area Loss Nationwide Percent of Production in Units Uni ts (in $) (in $) (1n $) Tota l Loss ---------------------------------------------------...--------------------------------.-.-----.....---------...-. 1 OOY. 311,201,667 cwt 1,945,010,417 205,406,904 2,150,417,321 9.6" 90Y. 280,081,500 cwt 1,750,509,375 166,379,593 1,916,888,968 8.n 80Y. 248,961,333 cwt 1,556,008,333 131,460,419 1,681,468,152 1.8:< 70Y. 217,841,167 cwt 1,361,501,292 100,649,383 1,462,156,675 6.9:< 60Y. 186,721,000 cwt 1,167,006,250 13,946,486 1,240,952,136 6.OX SOY. 155,600,833 cwt 912,505,208 51,351,726 1,023,856,934 5.OX 40Y. 124,480,667 cwt 778,004,167 32,865,105 810,869,271 4.1% I\,) 30Y. 93,360,500 cwt 583,503,125 '8,486,621 601,989,746 3.1:< .... 20Y. 62,240,333 cwt 389,002,083 8,216,276 397,218,360 2.1% 10Y. 31,120,167 cwt 194,501,042 2,054,069 196,555,111 1.0:< ------- $ (Mlilione) 2500 2000 1500 1000 l\) l\) 500 0 -500 0 50 Figure 6. Losses Due to Removal of Soybeans 100 150 200 250 BUSHELS OF SOYBEANS REMOVED (Mlliione) 300 - TOTAL WELFARE LOSS -*- DEADWEIGHT LOSS 4- LOSS OF REVENUES 350 ------- Table 9: Worksheet on soybeans INITIAL PRICE: INITIAL QUANTITY: INITIAL REVENUE: FA~ LEVEL PRICE ELASTICITY OF DEKAND: CHANGE IN QUANTITY: CHANGE IN PRICE: NEW PRICE: PERCENT CHANGE IN PRICE: CHANGE IN TOTAL REVENUE TO ALL FARMERS: LOSS OF REVENUES TO ILLINOIS: GAIN TO REST OF NATION'S SOYBEAN FARMERS: $6.25 $/BUSHEL 1,865,055,333 BUSHELS S11,656,595,833 -0.79 -17% (311,201,667)BUSHELS S1.32 S/BUSHEL S7.57 S/BUSHEL 21X S106,214,271 (S1,945,010,417) S2,051,224,693 --------------------------------------------------------------------------------- ---------- -------------------------------- PRODUCTION (;n bushels) YEAR 1983 1984 1985 ------------------------------------------------------------------ MEAN ILLINOIS U.S. 266,975,000 284,130,000 1,635,772,000 1,860,863,000 382,500,000 2,098,531,000 311,201,667 1,865,055,333 ----------------===----==================--========================--================ PRICE ($ per busheD YEAR 1983 1984 1985 ------------------------------------------------------------------ I1EAN ILLINOIS U.S. $7.94 S7.81 $5.85 $5.78 S5.35 S5.16 S6.38 S6.25 ======:=======---------------------------------------------------=---------====== 23 ------- Figure 7. Timing of Expenditures for Soybeans $ (Millions) 700 600 500 400 I\.J ~ 300 200 100 o M A M J J A SON D J F M A M J J A SON D J F MONTH -- VARIABLE COSTS -+- CUMULATIVE V. C. ------- Table 10: Welfare losses due to removal of snapbeans from market Farm Level Own Price Elasticity of Demand: -0.234 Amount of Commodity Removed -----.----------------.--------- Percent of Loss of Farm Dead Weight Tota l Dead Weight Largest Revenue in Welfare Welfare Loss al a State Affected Area Loss Nationwide Percent of Production in Units Uni ts (in $) (in $) (in $) Tota l Loss ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------.....-- 1 OOY. 231,543 tons 38,590,556 29,283,140 61,813,695 '3.1X 90Y. 208,389 tons 34,131,500 23,119,343 58,450,843 1oO.6X 80Y. 185,235 tons 30,812,444 18,141,210 49,613,654 31.8X 70Y. 162,080 tons 21,013,389 14,348,139 41,362,121 3'.1X 60Y. 138,926 tons 23,154,333 10,541,930 33,696,264 31.3X SOY. 115,772 tons 19,295,278 7,320,785 26,616,063 21.5X 40r. 92,611 tons 15,436,222 4,685,302 20,121,525 23.3X !\.) lJ1 30r. 69,463 tons 11,577,167 2,635,483 1',212,649 18.5X 20r. 46,309 tons 1,718,111 1,171,326 8,889,431 13.2X 1 or. 23,151, tons 3,859,056 292,831 4,151,887 1.1X ------- Figure 8. Losses Due to Removal of Snap beans $ (Millions) 70 60 50 40 30 I\J Q'\ 20 10 0 0 50 TONS OF 100 150 200 SNAP BEANS REMOVED (Thousands) ~ TOTAL WELFARE LOSS -*- DEADWEIGHT LOSS -+- LOSS OF REVENUES 250 ------- Table 11: Worksheet on snapbeans INITIAL PRICE: INITIAL QUANTITY: INITIAL REVENUE: FAR" LEVEL PRICE ELASTICITY OF DE~ND: CHANGE IN QUANTITY: CHANGE IN PRICE: NEW PRICE: PERCENT CHANGE IN PRICE: CHANGE IN TOTAL REVENUE TO ALL FAR"ERS: LOSS OF REVENUES TO : GAIN TO REST OF NATION'S FAR"ERS: S166.67 S/TON 652,003 TONS S1 08, 667, 222 -0.234 -36% (231,543)TONS S252.94 S/TON S419.61 S/TON 152% S67,76O,069 ($38,590,556) S1 06,350, 6210 --------------------------------------------------------------------------------- ------------------------- - -- ------------------------- YEAR 1983 PRODUCTION (in tons) 1984 1985 -------------------.---------------------------------------------- "EAN WISCONSIN U.S. 210,680 587,1010 235,130 666,110 248,820 702,1090 231,5103 652,003 ====:::================--=--===-----------------=====--=======--= YEAR 1983 PRICE (S per ton) 1984 1985 ------------------------------------------------------------------ "EAN WISCONSIN U.S. S1 100. 00 S16O.00 S152.OO S171.oo S152.00 S169.00 S148.00 S166.67 ==================--==========------==================--=======--==================== 27 ------- Table 12: Welfare losses due to removal of milk from market Farm Level Own Price Elasticity of Demand: Amount of Commodity Removed .....--------------------------- -0.32 Percent of Loss of Farm Dead IJeight Total Dead IJeight Largest Revenue in IJel fare IJel fare Loss asa State Affected Area Loss Nationwide Percent of Production in Units Uni ts (in $) (in $) (in $) Total LOll .-------.--.....--...----------.-..-.-------.-.-.------------------------.-.---------.-....-.-.......--...--...-. N co 100X 24,620,000,000 90X 22,158,0C>0,0C>0 80X 19,696,0C>0,0C>0 70X 17,234,00C>,0C>0 60" 14,772,000,000 50" 12,310,000,0C>0 40" 9,848,000,000 30" 7,386,000,000 20X 4,924,000,000 1 or. 2,462,00c>,00C> pounds pounds pounds pounds pounds pounds pounds pounds pounds pounds 3,139,050,0C>0 2,825,145,0C>0 2,~11,240,00c> 2t197,335,00C> 1,883,430,000 1,569,525,00C> 1,255,620,00C> 941,715,00C> 627,810,000 313,905,000 862,926,386 698,970,373 552,272,887 422,833,929 310,653,499 215,731,597 138,068,222 77,663,375 34,517,055 8,'29,264 4,001,976,386 3,524,115,373 3,063,512,887 2,620,168,929 2,1910,083,499 1,785,256,597 1,393,688,222 1,019,378,375 662,327,055 322,5310,264 21.6% 19.8% 18.OX 16.1% 14.2% 12.1% 9.9% 7.6% 5.2% 2.7% ------- Figure 9. Losses Due to Removal of Milk $ (Billions) 5 1 4 3 rv \0 2 o o 5 10 15 POUNDS OF MILK REMOVED (Billions) 20 25 ~ TOTAL WELFARE LOSS -*- DEADWEIGHT LOSS -+- LOSS OF REVENUES ------- Table 13: Worksheet on .ilk INITIAL PRICE: INITIAL QUANTITY: INITIAL REVENUE: FAR" LEVEL PRICE ELASTICITY OF DEftAND: CHANGE IN QUANTITY: CHANGE IN PRICE: NEW PRICE: PERCENT CHANGE IN PRICE: CHANGE IN TOTAL REVENUE TO ALL FAR"ERS: LOSS OF REVENUES TO WISCONSIN: GAIN TO REST OF NATION'S DAIRY FARHERS: $0.13 IPOUND 139,937,000,000 POUNDS $17,841,967,500 -0.32 (G&K, p. 64.) -18% (24,620, 000, 000) POUND $0.07 IPOUND $0.20 IPOUND 55% $4,944,628,478 ($3,139,050,000) $8,083,678,478 ----------------------------------- ----------- PRODUCTION (;n pounds) YEAR 1983 1984 1985 HEAN ----------------------~------------------------------------------- WISCONSIN U.S. n.a n.a n.a 24,620,000,000 24,620,000,000 n.a 139,937,000,000 139,937,000,000 -------- -------- -============================ PRICE ($ per pound) YEAR 1983 1984 1985 HEAN ------------------------------------------------------------------ WISCONSIN U.S. n.a n.a n.a n.a $0.12 $0.13 $0.12 $0.13 - --------- ------------------ 30 ------- 2.3.6 Lettuce Table 14, Figure 10, and Table 15 present the results for let- tuce. Seventy-two percent of all lettuce grown in the United States in 1983 through 1985 was grown in California. Coupled with an own price elasticity of -0.095 -- i.e., very inelastic demand -- a withdrawal of all of the California crop would increase prices by 754 percent -- from $ll.40/cwt. to $97.40/cwt. Total welfare loss would be $2.4 billion. Seventy-nine percent of this would be deadweight loss. Consumers would pay $1.5 billion in higher prices. 2.3.7 ~ Table 16, Figure 11 and Table 17 provide details of egg produc- tion. Although one state, California, produces more eggs than any other, the percentage of United States egg production that occurs there is only a modest 12 percent. Removal of this amount of eggs from the United States market would increase prices by 54 percent, from $0.65 per dozen to $1 per dozen. Farmers would lose about $441 million and there would be a dead weight loss of $120 million if 100 percent of California eggs were withheld from market. The dead weight loss would constitute a moderate 21 percent of total welfare loss nationwide. Dispersion of the egg crop keeps the relative magnitude of the dead weight loss low despite the very inelastic demand for eggs. 2.3.8 Chicken Table 18, Figure 12, and Table 19 provide the information regard- ing chicken. Price elasticity for chicken is a moderate -0.602, and only 16 percent of chickens are grown in the leading chicken state, Arkansas. A 100 percent removal of these chickens from market would increase prices by only 27 percent. Dead weight losses are 12 percent and less as the size of the removal is decreased. Increased prices would transfer $1.3 billion from consumers to farmers unaffected by the protective action. Total welfare loss would be $1.1 billion. 2.3.9 Beef Table 20, Figure 13, and Table 21 provide the results for beef. Although Texas produces the largest amount of beef, the percent- age of U.S. beef produced there is a relatively small 18 percent. The total welfare loss if all of this beef were removed from market would be over $6 billion, of which $5 billion would be lost revenue for impacted ranchers. The dead weight loss is under 18 percent. Consumers would pay an extra $10 billion in higher prices. This amount would be received by non-affected 31 ------- Table 14: Welfare losses due to removal of lettuce from market Farm Level Own Price Elasticity of Demand: -0.095 Amount 01 Commodity Removed .----.-.-.---------------------- Percent 01 Loss 01 Farm Dead lIeight Total Dead \/eight Largest Revenue in lIelfare lie l fa re Loss 85a State Affected Area Loss Nationwide Percent of production in Units Uni ts I (in $) (1n $) (in $) Total Lou ----------------------------------------------------.-----------------------.-.------.-.-------.........-.----.-- 100X 43,961,667 cwt. 501,163,000 1,890,296,007 2,391,459,007 79.0% 90X 39,565,500 cwt. 451,046,700 1,531,139,766 1,982,186,466 77.2% 80X 35,169,333 cwt. 400,930,400 1,209,789,445 1,610,719,845 75.1% 70X 30,m,167 cwt. ~50,814,1oo 926,245,044 1,277,059,144 72.5% 60X 26,377,000 cwt. 300,697,800 680,506,563 981,204,363 69.4% 50X 21,980,833 cwt. 250,581,500 472,574,002 723,155,502 65.3% 40r. 17,584,667 cwt. 200,465,200 302,447,361 502,912,561 60.1% t.J 30r. 13,188,500 cwt. 150,348,900 170,126,641 320,475,541 53.1% N 20X 8,792,333 cwt. 100,232,600 75,611,840 175,8104,440 43.0% 1 Or. 4,396,167 cwt. 50,116,300 18,902,960 69,019,260 27.4% ------- Figure 10. Losses Due to Removal of Lettuce $ (Millions) 2500 2000 1500 w w 1000 500 o o 10 20 30 40 CWT. OF LETTUCE REMOVED (Millions) - TOTAL WELFARE LOSS --*- DEADWEIGHT LOSS -+- LOSS OF REVENUES 50 ------- Table 15: Worksheet on lettuce INITIAL PRICE: INITIAL QUANTITY: INITIAL REVENUE: FARft LEVEL PRICE ELASTICITY OF OEKANO: $11.40 IC"T 61,343,667 C"T 1699,317,800 -0.095 CHANGE IN QUANTITY: -72% (43,961,667)C"T CHANGE IN PRICE: NE" PRICE: PERCENT CHANGE IN PRICE: CHANGE IN TOTAL REVENUE TO ALL FARKERS: $86.00 ICWT $97.40 ICUT 754% $993,644,986 LOSS OF REVENUES TO CALIFORNIA: GAIN TO REST OF NATION'S LETTUCE FARftERS: ($501,163,000) $1,494,807,986 PRODUCTION (;n c:wt.) YEAR 1983 1984 1985 flEAN ------------------------------------------------------------------ CALIFORNIA 41,689,000 47,273,000 42,923,000 43,961,667 U.S. 57,969,000 64,309,000 61,753,000 61,343,667 - -- - -------------- -------- PRICE ($ per cvt.) YEAR 1983 1984 1985 flEAH ------------------------------------------------------------------ CALIFORNIA U.S. $12.20 $12.30 $10.70 $11.00 $11.00 $10.90 $11.30 $11.40 -- ---------================= 34 ------- Table 16: Welfare losses due to removal of eggs from market Farm Level Own Price Elasticity of Demand: -0.22 Amount of Commodity Removed ---..--.----.--.-.--.-.--------- Percent of Loss of Farm Dead Weight Toul Dead Weight Largest Revenue in Welfere Welfare Loss asa State Affected Area Loss Nationwide Percent of Production in Units Units (in $) (in $) (in $) Tota l Lou -.-----------------.-.--------------------------------.---------------------------.-.-----------.....--------.-.. 1 oor. 682,375,000 dozens 441,496,625 120,265,412 561,762,037 21.4% 90r. 614,137,500 dozens 397,346,963 97,414,984 494,761,946 19.1X 80r. 545,900,000 dozens 353,197,300 76,969,864 430,167,164 17.9% 70r. 477,662,500 dozens 309,047,638 58,930,052 367,977,689 16.OX 60r. 409,425,000 dozens 264,897,975 43,295,548 308,193,523 14.OX SOX 341,187,500 dozens 220,748,313 30,066,353 250,814,665 12.OX w 40X 272,950,000 dozens 176,598,650 19,242,466 195,841,116 9.8% U1 30r. 204,712,500 dozens 132,448,988 10,823,887 143,272,875 7.6% 20r. 136,475,000 dozens 88,299,325 4,810,616 93,109,941 5.2% 1 Or. 68,237,500 dozens 44,149,662 1,202,654 45,352,317 2.1X ------- Figure 11. Losses Due to Removal of Eggs $ (Millions) 600 500 400 300 w 200 0\ 100 0 0 100 200 300 400 500 DOZENS OF EGGS REMOVED (Millions) - TOTAL WELFARE LOSS --*- DEADWEIGHT LOSS -+- LOSS OF REVENU ES 600 700 ------- Table 17: Worksheet on eggs INITIAL PRICE: INITIAL QUANTITY: INITIAL REVENUE: FARM LEVEL PRICE ELASTICITY OF DEMAND: CHANGE IN QUANTITY: CHANGE IN PRICE: NE'" PRICE: PERCENT CHANGE IN PRICE: CHANGE IN TOTAL REVENUE TO All FARMERS: lOSS OF REVENUES TO CALIFORNIA: GAIN TO REST OF NATION'S EGG RANCHERS: PRODUCTION (number of eggs) YEAR 1983 1984 ------------------------------------------------------------------ I1EAN CALIFORNIA U.S. n.8. 8,325,000,000 n.8. 68,230,000,000 ----------------------- ------------------------------------- SO.65 IDOZEN 5,693,208,333 DOZEN S3,683,505,792 -0.22 -12% (682,375,000)DOZEN SO.35 IDOZEN S1.oo IDOZEN 54% S1,324,775,392 ($441,496,625) S1,766,272,017 1985 8,052,000,000 68,407,000,000 8,188,500,000 68,318,500,000 PRICE ($ per dozen) YEAR 1983 1984 ------------------------------------------------------------------ I1EAN CALIFORNIA U.S. n.8. n.8. n.8. $0.72 1985 SO. 50 SO. 57 ------- SO.50 SO.65 ==============--==========================================================--======= 37 ------- Tabl. 18: W.Lf.~. lo.... due to removal of chicken fro. market Farm Level OWn Price Elasticity of Demand: -0.602 Amount of Commodity Removed ---..............-....-.-....-.- Percent of LoIS 01 Farm Dead lIeight Total Dead lIe1gM Largest Revenue in lIelfare \lelflre Lou a. a State Affected Area Lou Nationwide Percent of Production in Uniu Uniu (in $) (in $) (in $) Total Lou -----......-.-.-.-.-.--------.........-........-.-.-.----.-.-....-.-..-.-.......-.-...-.-.......---..-......---.. 100X 3,007,852,000 pounds 962,512,640 130,989,914 1,093,502,554 12.OX 90X 2,707,066,800 pounds 866,261,376 106,101,830 972,363,206 10.9X 80" 2,406,281,600 pounds 770,010,112 83,833,545 853,843,657 9.8X 70" 2,105,496,400 pounds 613,758,848 64,185,058 137,943,906 8.n 60" 1,804,711,200 pound. 577,507,584 47,156,369 624,663,953 7.5" 50X 1,503,926,000 pound. 481,256,320 32,747,478 514,003,798 6.4" t.J 40" 1,203,140,800 pound. 385,005,056 20,958,386 405,963,442 5.21 00 30X 902,355,600 pound. 288,753,792 11,789,092 300,542,884 3.9X 20" 601,570,400 pound. 192,502,528 5,239,597 197,742,125 2.6" 10" 300,785,200 pounds 96,251,264 1,309,899 97,561,163 1.3X ------- Figure 12. Losses Due to Removal of Chicken $ (Thousands) 1200 1000 800 600 w \0 400 200 0 0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 POUNDS OF CHICKEN REMOV'ED (Thousands) - TOTAL WELFARE LOSS ---r DEADWEIGHT LOSS -+- LOSS OF REVENUES 3500 ------- Table 19: Worksheet on cMcken INITIAL PRICE: INITIAL QUANTITY: INITIAL REVENUE: FARM LEVEL PRICE ELASTICITY OF DEKAND: $0.32 /POUND 18,356,867,000 POUNDS S5,874,197,~ -0.602 (G&K, p. 64.) CHANGE IN QUANTITY: -16% (3,OO7,852,000)POUND CHANGE IN PRICE: NEil PRICE: PERCENT CHANGE IN PRICE: CHANGE IN TOTAL REVENUE TO ALL CHICKEN PRODUCER SO.09 /POUND $0.41 /POUND 27% S374,365,738 LOSS OF REVENUES TO ARKANSAS: GAIN TO REST OF NATION'S CHICKEN PRODUCERS: (S962,512,640) S1,336,878,378 PRODUCTION (;n pounds) YEAR 1983 1984 1985 I1EAN ------------------------------------------------------------------ ARKANSAS n.a. 2,899,856,000 3,115,848,000 3,007,852,000 U.s. n.a. 17,862,944,000 18,850,790,000 18,356,867,000 -- ---------- PRICE ($ per pound) YEAR 1983 1984 1985 I1EAN ------------------------------------------------------------------ ARKANSAS U.S. n.a. n.a. SO.35 $0.34 $0.32 $0.30 $0.34 $0.32 = 40 ------- Table 20: Welfare losses due to removal of beef from market Farm Level Own Price Elasticity of Demand: -0.416 Amount 01 Commodity Removed ----...-.----------------------- Percent of Loss of Farm Dead Weight Total Dead Weight Largest Revenue in Welfare Welfare Loss as a State Affected Area Loss Nationwide Percent of Production in Units Uni ts (i n $) (in $) (in $) Total Loss -------------------------------------------------..----------------------------------------....-------------..... 100r. 7,048,237,941 pounds 5,156,710,837 1,093,568,337 6,250,279,173 17.5X 90r. 6,343,414,147 pounds 4,641,039,753 885,790,353 5,526,830,106 16.OX 80r. 5,638,590,353 pounds 4,125,368,669 699,883,735 4,825,252,405 14.5X 70r. 4,933,766,559 pounds 3,609,697,586 535,848,485 4,145,546,071 12.9X 60r. 4,228,942,765 pounds 3,094,026,502 393,684,601 3,487,711,103 11.3X 50r. 3,524,118,971 pounds 2,578,355,418 273,392,084 2,851,747,503 9.6X ~ 40r. 2,819,295,176 pounds 2,062,684,335 174,970,934 2,237,655,269 7.8X ~ 30r. 2,114,471,382 pounds 1,547,013,251 98,421,150 1,645,434,401 6.OX 20r. 1,409,647,588 pounds 1,031,342,167 43,742,733 1,075,084,901 4.1r. 1 Or. 704,823,794 pounds 515,671,084 10,935,683 526,606,767 2.1X ------- $ (Bllllon8) 7 6 5 4 ~ 3 (>.J 2 1 0 0 Figure 13. Losses Due to Removal of Beef 246 POUNDS OF BEEF REMOVED (Bllllon8) 8 - TOTAL WELFARE LOSS -*- DEADWEIGHT LOSS -f- LOSS OF REVENUES ------- Table 21: Worksheet on beef INITIAL PRICE: INITIAL QUANTITY: INITIAL REVENUE: FAR" LEVEL PRICE ELASTICITY OF DE~D: $0.73 S/POUND 39,946,992,000 POUNDS S29, 226, 466, 000 -0.416 CHANGE IN QUANTITY: -18% (7,048,237,941)POUNDS CHANGE IN PRICE: NEW PRICE: PERCENT CHANGE IN PRICE: CHANGE IN TOTAL REVENUE TO ALL FAR"ERS: SO.31 S/POUND S1.04 S/POUND QX S5,052,092,002 LOSS OF REVENUES TO KANSAS: GAIN TO REST OF NATION'S WHEAT FAR"ERS: (S5,156,710,837) S10,208,802,839 PRODUCTION (in pounds) YEAR 1983 1984 1985 MEAN ------------------------------------------------------------------ TEXAS n.a. n.a. 5,320,460,000 5,320,460,000 u.S. n.a. n.a. 39,946,992,000 39,946,992,000 ---- ------------------------- PRICE (S per pound) YEAR 1983 1984 1985 "EAN ------------------------------------------------------------------ TEXAS U.S. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. $0.78 SO.73 SO. 78 $0.73 ------------------- 43 ------- ranchers. Ranch level beef prices would increase from $0.73 per pound to $1.04 per pound. 2.3.10 Sweet Corn Table 22, Figure 14, and Table 23 provide the results for sweet corn. Thirty-one percent of this crop is grown in Florida. A total welfare loss of $89 million would occur if an amount of sweet corn of this magnitude were withdrawn from market. Of this amount, 32 percent, or $29 million would be dead weight loss. In addition to the dead weight loss consumers would loose nearly $130 million to farmers in higher prices. 2.3.11 Oranges Table 24, Figure 15 and Table 25 depict the results for oranges. Sixty-five percent of all oranges grown in the United States are now grown in Florida. Removal of this amount from market would increase farm level prices by 143 percent from $7.77 per box to $18.90 per box. Florida farmers would loose nearly $1 billion. Consumers would loose $0.7 billion in higher prices and another $0.7 billion in dead weight losses. The dead weight loss would be 42 percent of the total welfare loss nationwide of $1.6 billion. Just as the most severe impact on lettuce could only happen in California, the most severe impact on oranges could only happen in Florida. Other crops that are not as concentrated geographi- cally would have correspondingly smaller maximum repercussions from a single event. 44 ------- Table 22: Welfare losses due to removal of sweet corn from market Farm Level Own Price Elasticity of Demand: .0.32 Amount of Commodity Removed ----------....------------------ Percent of Loss of Farm Dead Weight Total Dead Weight Largest Revenue in Welfare Welfare Loss ua State Affected Area Loss Nationwide Percent 01 Production in Units Units (in $) (in $) (in $) Total Loss -----------------------------------------------------.-----------------------------------....-.----.---------.-.- 1 00r. 4,703,000 cwt. 60,041,633 28,635,886 88,677,520 32.3X 90r. 4,232,700 cwt. 54,037,470 23,195,068 77,232,538 30.OX 80r. 3,762,400 cwt. 48,033,307 18,326,967 66,360,274 27.6X 70r. 3,292,100 cwt. 42,029,143 14,031,584 56,060,728 25.OX 60r. 2,821,800 cwt. 36,024,980 10,308,919 46,333,899 22.2X ,c:,. 507. 2,351,500 cwt. 30,020,817 7,158,972 37,179,788 19.3X CJ1 407. 1,881,200 cwt. 24,016,653 4,581,742 28,598,395 16.OX 30Y. 1,410,900 cwt. 18,012,490 2,577,230 20,589,720 12.5X 20r. 940,600 cwt. 12,008,327 1,145,435 13,153,762 8.n 1 Or. 470,300 cwt. 6,004,163 286,359 6,290,522 4.6X ------- Figure 14. Losses Due to Removal of Sweet Corn $ (Millions) 100 ~ 0'\ 80 60 40 20 o o 123 4 OWT. OF SWEET CORN REMOVED (Millions) -- TOTAL WELFARE LOSS 4- DEADWEIGHT LOSS -+- LOSS OF REVENU ES 5 ------- Table 23: Worksheet on sweet com INITIAL PRICE: INITIAL QUANTITY: INITIAL REVENUE: FARft LEVEL PRICE ELASTICITY OF DEKAND: CHANGE IN QUANTITY: CHANGE IN PRICE: NEW PRICE: PERCENT CHANGE IN PRICE: CHANGE IN TOTAL REVENUE TO ALL FARftERS: LOSS OF REVENUES TO FLORIDA: GAIN TO REST OF NATION'S SWEET CORN FARMERS: - PRODUCTION (in cwt) YEAR 1983 1984 ------------------------------------------------------------------ FLORIDA U.S. 4,898,000 14,868,000 4,621,000 15,589,000 S12.77 !CWT 15,~7,667 CWT $196,704,544 -0.320 (G&K, RETAIL "oth vegitables., pp. -31% (4,703,OOO)CWT $12.18 !CWT $24.94 !CWT 95% $70,316,698 ($60,041,633) $130,358,332 1985 MEAN 4,590,000 15,766,000 4,703,000 15,~7,667 ----------------------------------------- PRICE (S per cwt) YEAR 1983 1984 ------------------------------------------------------------------ FLORIDA U.S. $12.80 $12.50 $13.~ $13.10 1985 MEAN $14.50 $12.70 S13.57 $12.77 --------------==-----------------------------;--------------------------------=== 47 ------- Table 24: Welfare losses d~e to removal of oranges from market Farm Level Own Price Elasticity 01 Demand: -0.455 Amount of Commodi ty Removed -------------------------------- Percent of Loss of Farm Dead lIeight Total Dead lIe;ght Largest Revenue in lIelfare Welfare Loss asa State Affected Area Loss Nationwide Percent of Production in Units Uni ts (in $) (in $) (in $) Total Loss ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------.------ 100:( 120,066,667 boxes 933,318,222 667,998,546 1,601,316,769 41.7X 90:( 108,060,000 boxes 839,986,400 541,078,823 1,381,065,223 39.2% 80:1. 96,053,333 boxes 746,654,578 427,519,070 1,174,173,647 36.4% 70:( 84,046,667 boxes 653,322,756 327,319,288 980,642,043 33.4% 60:( 72,040,000 boxes 559,990,933 240,479,477 800,470,410 30.0% 50X 60,033,333 boxes 466,659,111 166,999,637 633,658,748 26.4% 40X 48,026,667 boxes 373,327,289 106,879,767 480,207,056 22.3X ~ 30:( 36,020,000 boxes 279,995,467 60,119,869 340,115,336 n.7X (X) 20X 24,013,333 boxes 186,663,644 26,719,942 213,383,586 12.5X 10:( 12,006,667 boxes 93,331,822 6,679,985 100,011,808 6.7X ------- Figure 15. Losses Due to Removal of Oranges $ (Millions) 2000 1500 1000 01:0 \D 500 o o 20 40 60 80 100 BOXES OF ORANGES REMOVED (Millions) 140 120 -- TOTAL WELFARE LOSS --*- DEADWEIGHT LOSS -+- LOSS OF REVENUES ------- Table 25: Uorlcsheet on oranges INITIAL PRICE: INITIAL QUANTITY: INITIAL REVENUE: FARM LEVEL PRICE ELASTICITY OF DEKAND: S1.77 S/BOX 1M,3106,661 BOXES S1,'32,988,069 -0.'55 CHANGE IN QUANTITY: -65% (120, 066, 661) BOXES CHANGE IN PRICE: NEV PRICE: PERCENT CHANGE IN PRICE: CHANGE IN TOTAL REVENUE TO ALL FARMERS: S11.13 S/BOX S18.9O S/BOX 1103% (S218,066,'15) LOSS OF REVENUES TO FLORIDA: GAIN TO REST OF NATION'S ORANGE GROUERS: (S933,318,222) S115,251,1101 PRODUCTION (in boxes) YEAR 1983 19M 1985 MEAN ------------------------------------------------------------------ FLORIDA 139,600,000 116,100,000 103,900,000 120,066,661 U.S. 225,180,000 169,510,000 158,350,000 1M,3106,661 PRICE (S per box) YEAR 1983 1984 1985 MEAN ------------------------------------------------------------------ FLORIDA U.S. S6.85 S5.85 S1.11 S7.69 S9.65 S9.78 S8.01 S7.77 ----------------------------------------- - - 50 ------- 3. ANALOGOUS EVEHS Random events often cause supply ~eductions of the magnitudes described in section 2.3. In this section, these events are used to serve as a check on the calculated results of section 2.3 and to identify other issues of concern. For example, two of the crops studied, wheat and soybeans, were affected by the drought of 1988. 3.1 THE EXPERIENCE WITH SOYBEANS The drought of 1988 reduced that year's soybean production by about twenty percent, from 1,923 million bushels in 1987 to 1,539 million bushels in 1988,3 a 384 million bushel decrease. This compares to the 311 million bushel production by Illinois, the leading state in the production of soybeans, which accounts for 17 percent of the nation's soybean output. The predicted in- crease in price in section 2.3.3, based on a 17 percent reduc- tion, is 21 percent, to a high price of $7.57 per bushel. The change in price observed in 1988 was 25 percent, to an estimated $7.40 per bushel. Perhaps more notable than the fact that the predicted change in price is close to the actual change in price when the relative magnitudes of the reductions are taken into account, is the fact that year to year fluctuations in output of soybeans are some- times larger than the ones considered in this study. In the 8 years, 1981 through 1988, there were two such occurrences. In addition to the 20 percent drop in output due to the 1988 drought, a 25 percent drop in soybean output nationwide occurred in 1983. This drop in output was accompanied by a 40 percent increase in the price to nearly $8 per bushel. This means that the potential economic dislocations due to protective actions estimated in this study for soybeans are within the realm of common experience and that of existing data. 3.2 THE EXPERIENCE WITH WHEAT The drought of 1988 reduced the u.s. wheat harvest by 14 percent from the 1987-88 level of 2,107 million bushels to 1,811 million bushels in the 1988-89 season. This is slightly less than Kansas' production of 18 percent of the u.s. wheat crop. Wheat prices rose by about 45 percent between the 1987-88 season and the 1988-89 season. This is substantially less that the 72 percent increase predicted if Kansas wheat were removed from the market. However, if the calculation of section 2.3.1 were applied to a 14 percent reduction a 57 percent increase in price 3u. S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, "Table 7," Oil Cro~s. Situation and Outlook ReDort, OCS-21, April 1989, p. 33. 51 ------- would be predicted, which is closer to the 45 percent that happened. A 14 percent reduction in the u.s. wheat crop also occurred in the 1986-87 season. 52 ------- REFERENCES Baumol, William, Economic Theorv and ODerations Analvsis, 4th ed. (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, 1977), pp. 497-500. Hertel, Thomas W. and Marinos E. Tsigas, "General Equilibrium Analysis of Supply Control in U.S. Agriculture," Purdue University, April 1989. Hertel, Thomas W. et. al., "Competing Farm Level General Equilib rium Demand Elasticities for Agricultural Commodities," Research Bulletin No. 988 of the Agricultural Experiment Station, Purdue University, W. Lafayette, Indiana. Wohlgenant, Michael K., "Demand for Farm Output in a Complete System of Demand Functions," American Journal of Aaricultur- al Economics, May 1989, pp. 241-252. U. S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, "Table 7," Oil CrODS. Situation and Outlook ReDort, OCS-21, April 1989, p. 33. 53 ------- |