A Report on the
  SOCIOECONOMIC IMPACTS of the
  PROMULGATED TRANSPORTATION
    CONTROL PLAN  for SAN DIEGO
                          Prepared under
          BASIC ORDERING AGREEMENT 68-01-1551
                       TASK ORDER NO. 1
                            Prepared for
     ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY
                      FEBRUARY 20, 1974
                            Prepared by
(PMM&) PEAT, MAKWICK, MITCHELL & CO.
""

-------
                 PEAT, MARWICK, MITCHELL  & Co.
                                                          15446
                        1O25 CONNECTICUT AVE., N. Vf.

                         WASHINGTON. D. C. 2OO3G

                            February 20, 1974
 Mr.  Robert  Borlick
 Office of Planning and Evaluation
 Environmental Protection Agency
 1023 Waterside Mall
 Washington, B.C.  20460

 Mr.  David Calkins
 Region IX
 Environmental Protection Agency
 100  California Street
 San  Francisco, California 94111

 Gentlemen:

 This is a draft report of Phase I of the study of the socioeconomic  impact
 of the Air Quality Control Plan for San Diego promulgated by the Environ-
 mental Protection Agency on November 12, 1974.

 Authority for completing this work was received under Task Order #1  of
 Contract No. 68-01-1551 issued to Peat, Marwick, Mitchell & Co.  (PMM&Co.)
 and  subcontractor, the San Diego Comprehensive Planning Organization (CPO)
 on September 21,  1973.

 Primary objectives of this phase of the study are to assess the  economic
 and  social impacts which might result from implementing the EPA  promulgated
 plan,  and to assess the impact of selected alternatives to certain measures
 found  in Phase II of the study.  Phase I has been similar to a pilot study
 in the sense that it has developed methodologies for evaluating  costs,
 estimating measures, and assessing allocation techniques and socioeconomic
Devaluation data.  The project team feels that these data will be useful
 to EPA and other urban areas as a basis for the development of policy
 analysis and management tools.

 Initially, several cities were under consideration for pilot socioeconomic
 studies.  The major reasons San Diego was selected include:

        its detailed transportation planning networks and working data
        base that are suitable to support a modal split analysis that
        could be accomplished in a minimum amount of time;

-------
R M. M.&CO.
         Mr.  Robert Borlick
         Mr.  David Calkins
         February 20, 1974
         2
                 its location in an air quality control region where substantial
                 adjustment to travel habits or equipment is indicated on the
                 basis of present standards, monitoring results, and projected
                 growth patterns; and

                 its substantial sources of data, i.e., the air pollution control
                 studies previously completed in San Diego by EPA and the local
                 authorities, and the capability to provide assistance as a result
                 of prior modeling efforts.

         The study has proceeded generally as planned, except that major events
         have occurred since the study was authorized which have already influenced
         the future of the program.  On the one hand, a number of study findings
         (e.g., the estimated impact of the full surcharge program) will probably
         be of less concern to the San Diego Central Business District as a result
         of the new EPA position removing the mandatory requirement for that measure
         from the proposed plans.  On the other hand, the continuing discussions in
         Congress about increased relaxation of new automobile manufacturing require-
         ments and energy issues should heighten the interest and increase the value
         of findings relevant to these items.

         The transportation control measures were analyzed in considerable detail,
         and an evaluation of the impact of the EPA promulgated plan was completed
         utilizing projections of the San Diego regional transportation networks and
         modifications to the appropriate models for projecting travel changes
         resulting from the surcharge program and car pooling.  Trips are projected
         by type, time, and geographic locations relative to the income of the
         travelers in the San Diego region.

         Cost projections for all of the program measures were prepared for startup
         through 1966 and for continuing annual operating costs beginning 1977
         (assumed to be the first year of the implemented program).  San Diego costs
         were used where actual localized values could be found.  Cost related
         information was requested of EPA, all state and local organizations, and
         consultants known and obtainable.  PMM&Co.'s research revealed that a
         similar program management oriented cost estimate of the overall program had
         H£t__previously been attempted.  Substantial portions of the cost data used
         in our estimate were furnished by San Diego County and regional staffs.
         While every program cost has not been estimated and could not be developed
         within the scope of this effort, the project staff of PMM&Co. believes
         that the economic elements of major substance have been estimated, and
         that the elements involving as much as 80 to 85 percent of program costs
         of any socioeconomic significance have been identified.

-------
P. M. M.a CO.
         Mr. Robert Borlick
         Mr. David Calkins
         February 20, 1974
         3
         An initial attempt at developing a revenue flow,  representing  only the  first
         wave of the economic ripple effect, reveals an interesting group  impact in
         terms of net money flow as a result of the EPA promulgated plan.   This
         effect is identified to federal, state and local  government groups and
         also to the industry and consumer/citizen group.

         Phase I of the study reveals clearly the past difficulties in  reaching  an
         agreement or even a general consensus on the fundamental issues relative
         to health effects, rollback calculations, and other technical  difficulties
         not directly within the scope of this effort.  There are,  however, sig-
         nificant indications pointing both to a consensus on the degree of technical
         disagreement and to sufficient agreement on many  other issues.  In San  Diego,
         there is also substantial indication that an institutional transition
         phase is being reached by which program evaluation activities  are beginning
         to evolve into an organized program planning and  implementation phase.

         The project staff believes that future tasks should be designed to rein-
         force the further development of the San Diego program planning and
         implementation capabilities.  Section V outlinej3_briefly the major
         challenges to the program management stafl

         Information from many sources has been utilized in the preparation of  this
         report.  Among the sources employed were reports  published by  the Environ-
         mental Protection Agency and other governmental agencies,  consulting firms
         employed by EPA, the County of San Diego, and others.  Rand Corporation data
         was used in some cases as baseline information.  Although the  project  staff
         believes these sources to be reliable, we have not verified their data  and
         offer no opinion on the assumptions contained in  their work.  To  the extent
         that the information provided by such sources is  not accurate, or the
         assumptions they utilized are not realized, the projections may differ
         from future events.  In addition, changes in economic conditions, shifts in   x
         population, natural catastrophies and many other  uncertainties could
         adversely affect the projections.  Therefore, we  cannot represent the
         projections herein as future results that actually will be achieved.

         The terms of the contract are such that we have an obligation  to  submit a
         final report, but we have no obligation or intention to update or to revise
         that report, unless we are subsequently engaged to do so,  because of events
         occurring after the date of this draft report.

         Substantial assistance was provided to the PMM&Co. study team  by  members of
         the  San Diego  Task Force and by the EPA Project  Directors, Mr. D. Calkins
         of Region IX, and Mr. Robert Borlick of the Plans and Programs Office,
         Washington, D.C.                            -  -
                                                 Very truly yours,

                                                 PEAT, MARWICK, MITCHELL & CO.

                                                 fcJLJ'
                                                 John A. VfaiVder, Principal

-------
                        A Report on the
SOCIOECONOMIC  IMPACTS of the
PROMULGATED TRANSPORTATION
  CONTROL PLAN for SAN DIEGO
                         Prepared under
         BASIC ORDERING AGREEMENT 68-01-1551
                     TASK ORDER NO. 1
                          Prepared for
   ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY
                     FEBRUARY 20, 1974
                          Prepared by
    PEAT, MAKWICK, MITCHELL & CO.

-------
                           TABLE OF CONTENTS


SECTION                                                     PAGE


   I    OBJECTIVES OF THE SAN DIEGO STUDY                     1


  II    SUMMARY DISCUSSION OF FINDINGS AND CONCLUSIONS        8


 III    PRIMARY TASKS                                        14

          Impacts of the EPA Promulgated Transportation
          Control Plan Upon Travel Behavior                  14

          Development of Program Costs                       63

          Allocation Rationale                               86

          Revenue Analysis                                   98


  IV    IMPACTS OF STRATEGIES                               106


   V    PROGRAM IMPLEMENTATION                              109



Bibliography                                                HI


Appendix A                                                   A-l


Appendix B                                                   B-l


Appendix C                                                   C-l

-------
              I.  OBJECTIVES OF THE SAN DIEGO STUDY
 BACKGROUND

On March 20, 1973, by publication in the Federal Register, the
Administrator of the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) acting in
response to a court order, requested transportation control plans for
certain air quality control regions (AQCR).  By April 15,  1973,
California had not submitted a San Diego control strategy.  As a con-
sequence, EPA proposed substitute regulations for San Diego on July 16,
1973.  Considerable public discussion followed and the state submitted
Revision 3 of the California State Implementation Plan (SIP) on July 25,
1973.

EPA held public hearings on its plans in each affected AQCR.  Many
witnesses in the San Diego AQCR expressed the belief that  economic in-
centives and disincentives might reduce the vehicle miles  traveled
(VMT) more effectively than other measures, and that, as a bonus,
revenues could be produced for mass transit.  Among possible strategies
presented were to:

    .  increase surcharges on gasoline sales;

    .  establish surcharges on excessive automobile ownership
       involving related features such as weight, displacement; and

    .  place surcharges on facilities that house or service auto-
       mobiles.

It was emphasized that any scheme incorporating surcharges for parking
must extend beyond the urban central business district (CBD) in order
to keep core areas competitive with outlying employment and shopping
centers.

Significant controversy has existed in San Diego over two  particular
requirements under the Clean Air Act:

    .  Is the National Ambient Air Quality Standards (NAAQS) for
       photochemical oxidents (0.08 parts per million for  an hour)
       the appropriate standard; and

    .  Are socially disruptive measures, e.g., extensive gasoline
       rationing necessary by 1977 or might they be delayed?

Both of these points of controversy were discussed during  the hearings.

-------
While the November 12, 1973, plan promulgated for San Diego by EPA was
different from its earlier plan and plans generated by the local task
force and the California Air Resources Board, it was hoped that many of the
measures would be acceptable in the AQCR  and that alternate plans
developed by state agencies and the local task force could be approved
by EPA.

STUDY OBJECTIVES
A complete analysis of the social and economic effects of the Trans-
portation Control Plans (TCP's) had not been made due to time and
money constraints and the complexity of the problem.   On September 21,
1973, the Environmental Protection Agency contracted  with PMM&Co. to
conduct an initial socioeconomic impact study of the  EPA-promulgated
regulations for the San Diego Air Quality Control Region.  In partic-
ular, this study was to assess the several transportation control
measures initially promulgated and then to project the socioeconomic
effects of such controls.  In addition to providing information specific
to the San Diego plan, it was hoped that a systematic methodology for
assessing the socioeconomic impacts in other metropolitan areas of the
country could be developed and that the experiences of the San Diego
effort might be helpful to other urban AQCR efforts.

Overview of the Program Structure

Figure 1 identifies the major components of the program, indicates the
scope of institutional alignments which necessarily have been included
in the development of the study structure, and illustrates the basis
for the cost allocation rationale.  The major components of the socio-
economic program .structure include:

       program basis;

    ,  program strategies and measures;

       direct program cost groups; and

       cost allocations.

Program Basis

The initial component of the total study overview shown in Figure 1 is
the program basis.  In the context of this study,  the program basis in-
cludes those technical and environmental health issues which are the
basic underpinning of the entire air  quality control  program.   Some
of the major issues indicated are:

-------
    PROGRAM BASIS
      • HEALTH
      • MEASUREMENT
      • CALCULATIONS
      •TECHNICAL
       PROJECTIONS'
                       STRATEGIES
                      STATIONARY
                      MOBILE
                      VMT
 DIRECT PROGRAM  COSTS
      1
    LOCAL
 GOVERNMENT
      I
   STATE
GOVERNMENT
    I
  FEDERAL
GOVERNMENT
    I
                                 I
INDUSTRY
                                 1
CITIZEN
                 I
 • TAX RATES
              ALLOCATIONS
              • INCOME LEVEL
                          AUTO OWNERSHIP
                                 T
                    T
             $  BY HOUSEHOLD
                BY INCOME
                           % OF INCOME
                                      o/
                                      7o
          0    10    20   30    40
                       0    10    20    30    40
FIGURE 1:  AIR POLLUTION PROGRAM COST DISTRIBUTION METHODOLOGIES

-------
     .  the amount, types, concentrations, and time of exposure to
       those air pollutants which are considered detrimental to human
       health and other related objectives based on the values to our
       society which have supported the development of legislation,
       guidance, and standards;

       capabilities of measuring pollutant sources, concentrations,
       and dangers to the required degree of accuracy over time con-
       sistent with the prescribed standards; and

       the bases for projecting short and longer range pollution
       sources and quantities generated, as well as the projections
       of the cost and effectiveness of the technical and administra-
       tive measures proposed for corrective actions.

Program Strategies and Measures

As indicated on Figure 1, there are specific action areas identified
as those most likely and least costly in socially disruptive areas
which, if implemented effectively, would contribute to the solution
of reducing specific pollutants.

Past studies have been necessarily concerned with the medical, engi-
neering and legal facets of the program.  As progress is made and
additional facts are developed, increasing attention is now being
focused on the socio-economic and institutional impacts of the pro-
gram, and the practical feasibility and procedures involved in com-
pleting implementation and monitoring the effectiveness of the
programs.

These measures are categorized loosely into subgroupings identified
as:

     .  stationary sources—which include issues not directly related
       to travel-caused pollution, primarily industrial emissions;

     .  mobile sources—which generally refer to those measures and
       devices associated with mobile equipment;

     .  VMT reduction—which are measures generally related directly
       to reducing travel, or to measures which enhance efficiency of
       travel, or are now perceived to be measures which might be
       compatible with the overall objectives of the air pollution
       control program;

-------
     .  other measures—which include those not categorized above,
       including areas which might not be subject to local regulation,
       such as aircraft operations, both ground and local air,  rail
       and ship movements, and local mass transit operations.

Direct Program Cost Groups

Important components defined during the study are the cost groups. /
These groups reflect general institutional and societal arrangements
at a level where manageable and traceable socioeconomic discussions
of the relationship between the air quality control program measures
and the various segments of institutional groupings can be held.  It
was determined that cost data relevant to the directly identifiable
program costs could best be collected under five broad "cost  group-
ings."  These groupings are:

     .  local government—for the San Diego study, this title includes
       the City of San Diego, San Diego County within the AQCR and
       component organizations;

     .  state government--includes California and all state organiza-
       tions, procedures, and fiscal policies utilized in this study;

       federal government--includes the impact of funding and taxing
       programs plus granting programs and federal policies;

       industry—includes all AQCR industrial operations and is in-
       tended to incorporate other businesses directly affected by
       costs or revenues even though located outside the AQCR or the
       State of California; and

    .  citizen—includes all individuals directly affected by the
       air quality control program flow of funds or by eventual
       implementation of policies and regulations.

Cost Allocation Alternatives

No previous socioeconomic studies of these impacts on San Diego could
be found during literature reviews or subsequently through discussions
with EPA personnel or members of the San Diego Task Force.  It was con-
cluded that a cost allocation methodology would need to be developed
specifically for San Diego, but that the allocation rationale and
techniques would be adopted to reflect existing federal,  state, and
local fiscal policies.  In addition, industrially related costs would
be applied on the basis of present general business practice for those
segments affected.  It is believed that this methodology and alloca-
tion decision will provide maximum benefits for standard application
of socioeconomic evaluations to other programs and will provide the
best basis for subsequent program monitoring and evaluation efforts.

-------
 In consonance with this decision, costs for implementing the measures
 were considered to be one-time and nonrecurring.  Operating costs
 during  full  1977 application of the program were developed for each
 measure.  The estimated recurring costs are shown separately for each
 of the  five  groups:

 Allocation Procedures

 Several study tasks were directed toward the development of method-
 ologies and  the conduct of the cost allocations of this component of
 the study objectives.  Program costs were allocated from the defined
 groups  to determine impacts on the citizens on the basis of:

    .   household incomes;

    .   consumption patterns and travel habits by income groups; and

    .   present financial policies and practices of all levels of
        government and industry.

 On a group basis, a revenue analysis, at the same level as the program
 cost analysis, was completed to indicate the net revenue flow among
 groups.  This analysis also provided some additional insight into the
 proportions  of program funding expected to be assigned to various
 governmental components.  This subject is discussed in Section IV.

 A nonquantified procedure for analyses and sensitivity evaluations was
 developed to estimate the significance of strategies on selected user
 categories.  As an example, an analysis by the study team resulted in
 a judgment that for San Diego eleven of fifteen proposed measures
would result in the reduction of gasoline consumption.  This proce-
 dure applied to various groups or mixtures of groups could serve to
measure reaction sensitivities to a series of issues.  The approach
 is illustrated later in the report.

 The recent actions by the oil-producing and exporting countries and
 the resulting sudden public interest in petroleum and the general
 energy  issue have generated immediate and emotional responses by both
government and industry.  The Revisions to Surcharge and Management of
Parking Supply Regulations, released by EPA on January 15, 1974, elim-
 inates  the mandatory requirement for parking surcharges and modifies
parking supply management.  It also recommends that the "employer
 incentive" regulations are to be more generally worded.  Anticipated
energy  legislation is also concerned about these measures.

-------
This report is based on the impact of the EPA plan of November 12,
1973, for San Diego.  The strategies utilized are included in our
report as is the primary cost information obtained from the Environ-
mental Protection Agency, and the cooperating state and local organi-
zations .

It is expected that Phase II will emphasize the relative socio-
economic sensitivities, i.e., changes in strategies and related items,
such as increases in petroleum prices and extension of certain program
milestones.

A substantial amount of data utilized in this study had been developed
by the Office of Air Programs and others.  The designation of
Mr. Robert L, Borlick as  Project Director for the Office of Policy
and Planning and Mr. David Calkins for EPA's Region IX ensured utiliza-
tion of prior studies in Washington and improved access to Region IX
and San Diego data sources.

The San Diego County Comprehensive Planning Organization supported one
study of transportation measures as a subcontractor to PMM&Co. and the
San Diego County Air Quality Control District Office and the County of
San Diego Environmental Development Agency Office of Environmental
Management provided substantial data to the study team.

Additional assistance was provided by members of the County of San
Diego Air Pollution Task Force including the City of San Diego, the
San Diego Transit Corporation, the U. S. Navy, the State of California
Air Resources Board, and the State of California Department of Trans-
portation.

-------
      II.  SUMMARY DISCUSSION OF FINDINGS AND CONCLUSIONS

     This section includes a brief discussion of both the general
and the specific findings that are covered in the following sections
of this report and detailed in the appendices.  We have included
issues and needs pertinent to recent events and future implementation.
The findings and issues are summarized in three parts:

     0 general conclusions relevant to applicability of methodologies
       used in the study to other AQCRs;

     0 specific findings relative to the projected impacts of the
       Environment Protection Agency Promulgated Transportation
       Control Plan; and

     e future issues.
GENERAL CONCLUSIONS RELATIVE TO APPLICABILITY OF
METHODOLOGIES USED IN THIS STUDY TO OTHER AQCRs.

     At the outset of the study, one of the primary interests was
the potential development of methodologies and structures which might
be utilized as a semi-standardized procedure in other Air Quality
Control Regions (ACQRs).  In view of that interest, considerable
attention was given to the documentation of certain methods and
structures applied during the work.

     For example, an extensive bibliography of documents collected
during this study has been reviewed and an attempt has been made
to incorporate the advice and counsel obtained during our discussions
with organizations extending from EPA through all levels of state
and local government agencies to technical consultants and selected
industry representatives.

     It was found that substantial cost information had been
developed during prior studies and that with considerable restructuring,
portions of those estimates could be utilized as a basis for this
report.   However, the general application of national average
information was not acceptable, and, as a result, locally developed
values were selected for a number of the cost and socioeconomic
elements.  Price estimates of program costs failed to segregate
start-up and operating costs and tended toward theoretical fiscal
and economic assumptions.  Consequently, a consistent program
framework and ground rules on cost allocations and projections were
required.  A program structure (Figure 1) and defined ground rules
for cost groups were developed.

     The program components, cost and revenue groups, and basic
allocation techniques applied in this study can be expected to be

-------
uniformly applicable to all AQGRs, and could be readily applied by
local and regional task forces developing AQCR program plans.
However, actual values and ratios would be expected to vary.
Similar standardized formats will need to be generally described and
accepted if state, regional, or federal program evaluation and
monitoring procedures are to be meaningful.

     A decision was made to allocate costs in accordance with existing
financial policies affecting the citizens of San Diego.  Application
of existing policies will be required if meaningful programs are
to be developed for maintaining a national and regional evaluation
and regulatory policy compatible with actual state and local program
planning and management priorities.

     At the start of the study, particular interest existed in the
potential usefulness of existing models that associated control
measures with existing transportation data.  While an appraisal of
existing and new models was not a part of the study, several current
efforts to evaluate or develop air pollution monitoring models and
related tools were reviewed during the work.  Specific discussions
were held with representatives of the National Science Foundation,
the Lawrence Livermore Laboratory of the University of California, and
San Diego County.  The MOVEC model developed by the Rand Corporation
was utilized to provide specific data items in support of this
study effort.

     Discussions of transportation models are detailed in later
portions of this report.   From the results of this study, it
appears that a potential for application of such transportation
models exists in those specific AQCRs where substantial transportation
planning networks have already been developed.  It might eventually
be desirable to categorize specific AQCRs possessing such transpor-
tation information into groups having similar travel characteristics.
A selective study program may produce sufficient information for
cities so that extrapolations of certain travel behavior might be
accomplished for critical issues with some additional degree of
confidence.  Potential cities where such studies might be conducted
are Boston, Denver, Baltimore, and Atlanta.

     One issue that should be considered prior to determining the
need for these additional studies is the existing degree of accuracy
and relative impact of other program components (e.g., costs and
mechanisms of major car-pooling programs, potentials of massive
public supported urban transit systems, or new socioeconomic incentives
or penalties such as the four-day work week).  _

-------
SPECIFIC FINDINGS RELATIVE TO THE PROJECTED IMPACTS OF
THE TRANSPORTATION CONTROL PLAN

     A summary of the most significant transportation conclusions
discussed in Section III follows.

     0 Application of the surcharge would result in a reduction of
       vehicle miles traveled (VMT) of approximately 12 percent.
       EPA calculations included in the promulgated plan for San
       Diego indicate that a greater reduction, of approximately
       30 to 33 percent, achieved through other measures will be
       required to meet the standards.

     0 The surcharge program would result in a greater travel
       mobility penalty being imposed on people living within the
       San Diego central zone than on people living in more
       outlying zones.

     0 The factors contributing to the reduction in VMT in order
       of decreasing importance are:

       0 increase in car pooling,

       0 foregone trips (excluding work trips which would not be
         reduced), and

       0 diversion from automobile to mass transit.

     0 The average travel time for individual trips in each of the
       six San Diego major statistical areas  (MSA) are as follows:

                 MSA        Transit System        Automobile Travel
                              (Minutes)              (Minutes)

0
1
2
3
4
5
6
Base
29
39
28
45
19
0
31
Plan
31
37
29
41
21
0
32
Base
13
14
14
16
17
32
14
Plan
14
16
16
17
18
34
16
                                   10

-------
       The total travel time for people traveling within the San
       Diego region increases marginally, 3 percent, even though
       person-trips and person-miles of travel decreases.

       There is a direct recurring cost of $351 million expressed in current
       dollars by the parking surcharge andmass transit _ingfntive
       measures.  If one half this amount were dedicated to improving
       local mass transit, a substantial expense/revenue system
       imbalance would probably result.

     Numerous additional findings and conclusions are contained in the
transportation discussions and in the appendices to the report.
Selected findings discussed in Section III relative to the develop-
ment and allocation of costs are:

     0 Considering all measures and groups selected, a total of
       132 cost elements were identified where some cost impact
       might be incurred.  Of these, 116 cost items were developed
       with the assistance of the groups identified in the study.  On
       the basis of information furnished, it is expected that these
       items represent the substantial majority of the program
       costs.  However, data for sixteen items was not available
       or was not sufficiently supportable to be included.

     0 The economic impact on individual citizens would be severe
       if the surcharge program were to be implemented as promulgated.
       The total program costs (in current dollars) to citizens
       by household income accumulated through 1977 would be as
       follows:
                         Implementation
     Household Income    	Costs	    Recurring Costs    Total Costs

     $0 - 5,000               $22               $599             $621

     $5,000 - 10,000           29                803              832

     $10,000 - 15,000          40              1,012            1,052

     $15,000 and over          71              1,276            1,347

     0 Stationary measures represent the most cost effective strategy.
       These could be implemented with virtually no net cost to
       industry or the consumer.  In addition,_an annual savings
       of petroleum will be achieve^ through conservation equipment.

     0 The mobile source program would cost approximately $54 million
       for equipment, installation,  and construction and would have approximately
       $31 million in recurring costs.   There is a manpower question


                                   11

-------
       regarding the feasibility of training sufficient inspection
       and particularly maintenance personnel by 1977 due to the
       high degree of proficiency required to service the complete
       range of retrofitted and new vehicles equipped with increasingly
       complex devices.  Examination of longer range (beyond 1977)
       considerations of retrofitted vehicle life reveals that this
       measure appears to represent one of the least cost effective
       approaches.  In addition, an annual increase in petroleum
       consumption of approximately $6 million per year is anticipated.

     0 Without the surcharge, an increase of the mass transit system
       to 550 buses would result in a recurring deficit of approximately
       $23 million.

     Specific findings discussed in Section IV relate to the social
impact of strategies on unique interest groups.

     0 No effective procedures have been found for reviewing with
       the citizens Complex socioeconomic issues of the air quality
       control program.

     0 Little in-depth socioeconomic evaluation of a four-day work
       week has been referenced in prior EPA or other studies of
       alternate feasible strategies or measures.

     0 Substantial additional work will be required to refine and
       develop the appropriate content and procedures for
       evaluating and accurately summarizing the majority opinions
       and optimum socioeconomic measures preferred by other AQCRs
       where such a tool might productively be employed.   A similar
       structure would also assist in communications and presentations
       for federal, state, and local legislative bodies.

     0 The timing of issuance of evaluation procedures, to be of
       benefit to other AQCRs, should be expedited.  The procedures
       and formats should be prepared in a clear,  concise, untechnical
       manner to be easily comprehended and followed.   Standardization
       will aid evaluators and program management  to compare
       attitudes and reactions in different AQCRs  and to facilitate
       implementation.

     0 Program implementation, cost, and socioeconomic data are
       developmental in nature.   However, the study team believes
       that this study has established that uniform program evalua-
       tion and planning criteria and procedures can be accomplished.
       The selection of next-step AQCRs should involve more than
       our example and should include consideration of several
       characteristics such as:
                                   12

-------
       0 the variety and availability of transit options,

       0 the size of the metropolitan area,

       0 different government structured interfaces, and

       0 different energy supply situations.

     It is recommended that EPA offer to provide financial and
technical assistance to develop implementation programs in AQCRs in
several states.

FUTURE ISSUES

     Energy conservation and air pollution control can be viewed as
compatible, not competing programs.  Seventy-three percent of the	
measures considered in the San Diego air pollution control program
were estimated to promote gasoline savings.  An assessment of
Energy impacts relate3~To~envirbnmental consequences could include
considerations such as:

     0 Positive impacts including increased transit usage, increased
       car pooling, and decreased numbers and lengths of trips;

     0 Indeterminate impacts including increased usage of smaller ^
       vehicles and revised scheduling and timing of trips; and

     0 Negative impacts including increased idling of vehicles
       waiting in line for gasoline, increased driving in search
       of gasoline, and increased gasoline consumption by retrofitted
       vehicles.

     Thus, new and innovative joint energy conservation—air pollution
control programs should be designed and implemented.
                                 13

-------
                         III.  PRIMARY TASKS
 IMPACTS OF THE EPA PROMULGATED  TRANSPORTATION CONTROL PLAN UPON
 TRAVEL BEHAVIOR

 Introduction

      An analysis of the  impacts of  the EPA promulgated transportation
 control plan upon travel behavior and the transportation system in the
 San Diego region is presented in this part of Section III.  In this
 analysis, "impact" is  defined as the difference between the transporta-
 tion system and travel patterns which would have existed in the San Diego
 metropolitan area on July 1, 1977,  had the transportation control plan
 not been promulgated (i.e., the base system); and the transportation
 system and travel patterns which would exist in the San Diego region at
 this same date were the  transportation control plan promulgated by the
 EPA on November 12, 1973,  to be implemented (i.e., the EPA plan).  The
 analysis is structured to  analyze differential impacts upon various
 strata of residents of San Diego — as defined in terms of household in-
 come and geographic location within the region.

      Distinguishing between the base and the EPA plan, which are both
 conceptually straight  forward,  was  particularly difficult with respect
 to  locally implemented measures proposed to meet EPA's air quality
 standards.

      Various highway,  public transit, and bike system improvements were
 planned  for the San Diego  region prior to promulgation of the transporta-
 tion control plan.   In several  cases, it was difficult to assess whether
 transporation facilities and services were planned due to the EPA program,
 or  whether implementation  schedules of previously planned projects were
 accelerated to  satisfy EPA's air quality standards.  To the greatest
 possible extent,  the reasonableness of the treatment of base and EPA plan
 definitions was checked  through conversations with appropriate local
 officials  and EPA representatives.  These assumptions are documented in
 subsequent  sections  of this chapter.

     The  principal  criteria used to measure the travel behavior impacts
 of  the promulgated  plan  are the passenger miles of travel and number of
 daily  trips  made  by  automobile drivers,  automobile passengers, and transit
 passengers.   The  principal criteria used to assess the changes in the
 service  provided  by  the  transportation system are travel time (accessibility)
 and  travel  costs  for the study area travelers.

Description of  the Base  System

     The regional transportation planning data base which had previously
been assembled  for  the San Diego region  by CPO was utilized as a basis for
analysis of  the transportation measures.   In conducting its long-range
planning activities, CPO had developed an extensive data base for the 1975
time frame which has been used to evaluate the implications of a number
of different land-use  transportation development programs for the region
in the period between  the 1975 base case and the 1995 forecast year.
                                 14

-------
     The  following data files were obtained from CPO:

        1975 higlway network;

        1975 transit network;

        the trip tables with forecasts of interzonal travel for
        1975 for five trip purposes;

        total employment and the number of employees in each zone
        working for employers with more than one hundred employees
        (the number of employees working for employers with less than
        100 employees was derived from these employment estimates);

        the distribution of traveler's household incomes by zone of
        residence; and

        the most recent version of a computer program for applying the
        modal split and automobile occupancy models currently used by CPO.

These data sets were reviewed in detail by the project team for con-
sistency with the requirements of this study.  Updates and adjustments
made to the CPO's data base, modal split, and automobile occupancy models
to create and analyze the base and plan transportation systems in the
region are presented below.


Base System

     Highway Network

     The highway network incorporated all of the highway improvements
anticipated to be opened to traffic in 1975 at the time that CPO prepared
the network.  The following modifications were implemented to develop a
network that corresponded to the highway system as it is currently ex-
pected to be in operation on a ten-mile section of Westbound State High-
ways 125-94 between 1-8 and 1-5.  Autombile traffic entering the freeway
will be delayed to the extent necessary to prevent the volume on the main-
line lanes of the freeway from becoming large enough to slow the flow of
traffic below 50 mph.  Based on discussions with California Department of
Transportation personnel, it was assumed that each automobile would be
delayed an average of three minutes prior to entering the freeway.  After
entering the freeway, vehicles would travel at an average speed of 50 mph.
It is anticipated that preferential treatment would be given to buses
utilizing the affected freeway on-ramps and that buses would therefore not
encounter the three-minute delays at the on-ramps.
                                  15

-------
     Specific projects and their relevance to our project are listed
below:

        Ramp metering projects are expected to be implemented at
        four westbound on-ramps along Interstate 8 between Interstate 15
        and State Route 125.  A three-minute delay was also assumed
        for each automobile using these on-ramps.

        State Route 252 — a proposed freeway connecting Interstate
        805 and Interstate 5 between National Avenue and Division
        Street — was not included in the base network because this
        route will probably not be available to traffic by July 1, 1977.

        Mera Mesa Boulevard, which is proposed to be constructed west
        of Interstate 15 north of the Miramar Naval Station, was not
        included in the network because it is not anticipated to be
        completed by July 1, 1977.

        The proposed interchange at Johnson Street and Interstate 8
        was included in the 1977 highway network, but the direct
        ramp from eastbound Interstate 8 to northbound State Highway
        67 was not.

        The remaining highway improvements which have been planned for
        the San Diego region had already been incorporated~into the
        base 1975 highway network prepared by CPO.l

     Highway Operating Policies

     Estimates of all-day parking costs for each zone in the San Diego
region for 1975 and 1995 were provided by CPO.  An estimate of parking
costs for each zone for 1977 was developed by linearly interpolating between
the 1975 and 1995 estimates.  For those zones in which CPO estimated
that there would be a parking fee in 1995 but that parking would be free
in 1975, it was assumed that parking would be free in 1977.

     Considerable uncertainty exists with respect to both the supply and
price of gasoline in the immediate future, and there is even greater un-
certainty with regard to these factors in the analysis year of 1977.  For
the purposes of this analysis, it was assumed that sufficient gasoline
supplies would be available in 1977 to satisfy the demands for gasoline
resulting from autombile driving — that is, that no gasoline rationing
schemes would be in effect because of limited supplies.
1.  Cleaning of the Air, Local Transportation Control Plan for the San
Diego Air Basin; San Diego Air Pollution Control Task Force;  San Diego,
California, October 1973.
                                 16

-------
     The price of gasoline in 1977 was estimated by projecting the
November 1973 price of 41.9 cents per gallon for regular gasoline to
1977 assuming a 4.5 percent annual increase in the cost of gasoline.
An additional 15 cents was added to the 1977 cost per gallon of gasoline
to account for the possibility of significantly higher gasoline prices
in 1977.  The resulting cost of gasoline was approximately 65 cents per
gallon.  The cost per gallon was discounted to 1966 dollars for use in
the modal split model and converted into a cost per mile using an average
gas consumption rate of 13.22 miles per gallon.  A price surcharge was
also added to the per mile cost of oil to account for possible price
increases through 1977.  It was further assumed that out-of-pocket costs
for automobile maintenance and tires would increase at the same rate as
consumer prices.  The resulting 1977 cost of operating an automobile ex-
pressed in 1966 dollars is 5.5 cents per mile.  This figure was used in
both the base and plan system modal split analyses.

     Transit Network

     The 1975 CPO transit network included the existing bus system as
well as a number of improvements to the 1973 system.  In particular,
it incorporated the remaining six routes of a nine route express bus
system which is being developed by San Diego Transit Corporation (SDTC).
The express routes that it is assumed would be implemented by 1975 are:

        express route 1-La Jolla-Pacific Beach;

     .  express route 4-Lakeside El Cajon-La Mesa;

        express route 6-Casa de Oro-Spring Valley-Lemon Grove;

     .  express route 7-San Ysidro-Chula Vista;

        express route S-I^perial Beach-Chula Vista-National City;
        and

     .  express route 9-Santee-El Cajon.

     The size of SDTC's bus fleet was expected to increase from its
current size of 250 buses to 350 buses by fiscal year 1977-78 to serve
the planned local and express bus system.    Bus service within the San
Diego area is also operated by the Oceanside Transportation System,
Chula Vista City Lines, San Diego Economy Lines, and Weston Greyhound
Lines, although the San Diego Transit Corporation is the major carrier
within the region.  Based on a review of the 1975 transit network and
discussions with transit officials and planners in the San Diego region,
it was concluded that the 1975 CPO transit network represented the base
transit system as defined in this study (i.e. , the system which would
be in operation in 1977 were the EPA plan not to be implemented).
 1. Transit Development Plan and Program, Fiscal 1972-1973 Update;
   San Diego Comprehensive Planning Organization and California;
   May 1973.

                                 17

-------
     Transit Operating Policies

     On September 1, 1972, SDTC established a single fare of 25c
with free transfers for travel to all destinations within the region.
Transfer privileges were improved in that the time interval of one hour
between transfers was raised to three hours with stop-over privileges
on the same route.  Based on discussions with personnel at SDTC,  it was
assumed that the 25
-------
        A system to provide preferential treatment to buses and
        high-occupancy automobiles is to be implemented at the
        entrance ramps of selected freeway sections.   These were
        the same sections of freeway for which the California
        Department of Transportation was planning to  implement
        the ramp metering system and included:

            California State Highway 125 from Interstate 8 to
            its junction with California State Highway 94; and

            California State Highway 94 from the junction with
            California State Highway 125 to the junction with
            Interstate 5.

     Car-Pool Matching

     The plan highway and transit networks were appropriately modified
to reflect these projects.  The travel time for buses on Broadway was
reduced and this street was removed from the highway  network.  It was
assumed that buses and high-occupancy automobiles would encounter no
delays upon entering freeways whereas low-occupancy automobiles would
encounter an average of a three-minute delay, as noted above.

     A computerized car-pool matching system that is  conveniently-
available to the general public and to all employees  of businesses
having more than 100 employees is to be implemented in the San Diego
region.  This system is designed to provide information to home-to-work
travelers regarding other travelers who have similar  origins, destinations,
and travel schedules thereby enabling the travelers to form car pools.
The availability of a high-quality car-pool matching  system is an essential
element of any program to improve automobile occupancy for home-to-work
travel.

     Parking Supply Management

     The EPA plan includes a program to require EPA approval of any
significant additions to the supply of parking facilities in the San Diego
region.  It would be incumbent upon the developer of  a parking facility
to demonstrate that the proposed facility would not prevent or interfere
with the attainment or maintenance of any national air quality standard
at any time within ten years from the date of application.  The level of
detail required in the developer's submittal is dependent upon the size
of the proposed facility with one level of detail being required for
projects which would increase capacity by 50 to 249 vehicles and a greater
level of detail required for projects which would increase capacity by
250 or more vehicles.
                                  19

-------
      The availability of parking facilities could have an important
 impact upon the travel choices of urban residents — particularly if
 the supply of parking facilities is insufficient to serve the demand
 at particular locations or at particular time periods.  Thus, this
 measure could have an important impact upon traveler decisions if the
 number of automobile trips were to significantly increase.   Inasmuch
 as the measure only controls increases in parking capacity and no
 rollbacks in the supply of parking are required elsewhere in the  EPA
 plan, the impact of the parking supply management measures is more
 limited if the demand for parking does not increase.  Since the EPA
 plan is designed to decrease significantly the volume of automobile
 travel in the San Diego region, it is assumed that this measure would
 not be a constraint upon automobile travel~or mode choice in the  time
"Trame of this study.

 Mass Transit Incentives for Employees

      The provisions of this measure impact primarily upon "large"
 employers — where a large employer is defined as maintaining more
 than 70 parking spaces.  Employers in this category are required  to
 implement two programs — a surcharge program and a reimbursement
 program.

      The parking surcharge program has differential rates for varying
 levels of automobile occupancy as follows:

         one-person automobiles - daily parking surcharge of
         $2.50 plus a commercial parking rate, if applicable;

         two-person automobiles - fifty percent of the cost of
         one-person automobiles;

         three-person automobiles - no parking cost (i.e., either
         commercial or surcharge) and the allotment of those parking
         spaces located closest to the employment facility.

 The large employer, in addition to charging the parking surcharges,
 is required by the EPA plan to charge the average daily commercial rate
 charged by the three operators of parking facilities each containing
 100 or more commercial spaces within two miles of the employer.  If
 the large employer is more than two miles from such commercial facilities,
 only the parking surcharge is to be charged.   This effectively means that
 large employers within two miles of the San Diego CBD would be required
 to charge their employees who drive to work a commercial parking  rate plus
 the applicable parking surcharges.  The average commercial parking rate
 used to estimate total daily parking cost was the average daily parking
 charge in zones on the periphery of the CBD.   The differences in  parking
 costs by automobile occupancy class and by location of the large  employer
 relative to the San Diego CBD have been incorporated in the inputs to the
 plan modal split analysis.
                                   20

-------
      Reimbursement was considered  to  all  employees using public  transit
 service to and/or from work of  the first  $200  per year of  their  transit
 fares.   Since transit fare was  assumed  to be 25
-------
     The EPA surcharge measure relating to free parking facilities
imposes a regulatory fee of $450.00 per year per space upon each owner
or operator of more than five free parking spaces including free on-
street parking spaces outside of residential areas.  The amount of
this fee was determined by calculating the annual proceeds of a 25c per
hour surcharge — the same as imposed on commercial parking spaces —
and assuming a 250-day year and a 60  percent average occupancy for each
space during the days and hours for which the fee is collected.  This
measure impacts the majority of workers in San Diego inasmuch as about
75 percent of the workers in San Diego are employed by employers with
less than 100 employees and 90 percent of the employees in the region
are provided with free parking facilities.  (Commercial parking spaces
in the San Diego region are located largely in the CBD, and less than 10
percent of the workers in the region are employed there.)  Similarly,
this is the parking surcharge measure that would have the greatest impact
upon nonwork travel in the San Diego region inasmuch as well over 90 per-
cent of the nonwork travel in the region is not oriented to the CBD.  In
effect, this measure would impose a parking surcharge upon the large
number of free parking spaces provided by commercial, recreational, and
even religious organizations.  Any organization providing free parking
facilities for use for other than parking by residents of a structure
would be subject to this surcharge.

     The surcharge on free parking spaces is the only surcharge which is
imposed upon the owner and operator of the facility rather than upon the
parker.  In assessing the impact of this measure upon travel behavior,
it is necessary to consider whether this surcharge will be imposed
directly or indirectly upon the traveler.  For example, if a shopping
center pays the surcharge from its operating budget and correspondingly
increases the price of the goods sold to the travelers — the traveler
would not directly perceive the cost of parking in making his travel
decisions.  On the other hand, if a parking meter to collect a surcharge
of 25
-------
travel analysis should assess the combined effects of all of the EPA
measures — save the limitations upon gasoline consumption.   In this
manner, the analysis provides an initial assessment of whether such
limitations upon gasoline consumption are required.  If such limitations
were required, the impact of these upon travel patterns in the San Diego
region will be assessed in subsequent phases of this project.

     Locally Implemented Measures

     The EPA plan takes note of a series of locally implemented strategies
as being applicable toward attainment of the oxidant standard and encourages
their implementation, although the reductions are not credited as part of
the EPA plan.  Inasmuch as EPA recognized that the locally implemented
measures will be considered in assessing progress toward attainment of
the oxidant standard, these locally implemented measures were incorporated
in this analysis.  Only those locally implemented measures which would
result in incremental changes to the base 1977 transportation systems
described above are considered in this section.

     Bus System Improvements

     The following bus system improvements are proposed as part of the
locally implemented improvements:

     .  Purchase of an additional 200 buses to improve the level
        of service and expand geographic coverage of the public
        transit system in the San Diego region.  These buses would
        be in addition to the 350 buses which were planned for operation
        in the San Diego region in 1977 prior to the advent of the EPA
        transportation control plan.

     .  An exclusive bus by-pass lane would be constructed to allow
        buses traveling through Balboa Park onto State Highway 163
        northbound to by-pass existing traffic congestion.  The
        estimated two to five minutes savings in travel time for
        buses using the by-pass lane was appropriately incorporated
        into the analysis.

        A set of express transfer facilities has been proposed at
        freeway ramps on reconstructed Interstate 15 — the Escondido
        Freeway.  It is proposed that each transfer facility be equipped
        with a parking lot for approximately 200 cars and secure facilities
        for bicycle storage.   Provision is being made for the construction
        for three such facilities — at Mira Mesa Boulevard (which would
        be constructed first as a demonstration project), at Poway Road,
        and Rancho Vernardo.  The locally implemented plan notes that
        20 such lots strategically located throughout the region could
        have the potential for reducing daily vehicle miles of travel but
        that the likelihood of implementing such a system by the year 1977
        seems remote.  Based on these considerations, only the fringe
        parking facility at Mira Mesa Boulevard was incorporated into the
        analysis of travel patterns.


                                  23

-------
        Two non-capital intensive programs are proposed:

           a comprehensive marketing program — incorporating
           scheduling, schedule information, system maps, and
           information — designed to increase public awareness
           of the public transportation system; and

           allowing employers to purchase transit tickets at
           reduced cost and provide them to their employees to
           encourage the employees to utilize transit travel to
           work.

     An assessment of the impact of the 200 additional buses upon
travel patterns within the San Diego region requires that the services
provided by these buses—that is the routes and schedules of the busses—
be described in detail.  Discussions with planning personnel of SDTC did
not at this time have specific recommendations regarding the utilization
of these additional 200 buses.  The SDTC planning personnel indicated
that priority in the allocation of the additional buses would be given
to providing additional service on (1) those existing bus routes which
were currently experiencing over-crowding of buses and (2) reducing
headways on those existing routes with excessive headways.  A listing of
the peak hour and midday period headway changes to the existing routes
and the proposed express routes which would result from implementation
of these guidelines is presented in Table 1.

     In addition, the following new bus routes were included in the plan
transit network:

        feeder bus service connecting Scripps Ranch to Route 6;

        feeder bus service connecting the Tierra Santa area to
        proposed express route 9; and

        shuttle bus service from San Diego Stadium to the San Diego
        Central Business District running on ten minute headways
        during the peak hours of travel.
                                24

-------
                               TABLE 1

                     1977 BASE AND PLAN CONDITION
                          BUS  ROUTE HEADWAYS
Bus Route
1
2
3
4
5
5X
6
7
9
11
11X
12
Express Rt. 1
Express Rt. 4
Express Rt. 6
Express Rt. 7
Express Rt. 8
Express Rt. 9
B
C
E
_F
G
H
J
K
L
0
0-1
R
T
S. D. Economy Line
Bus Route Headways (Minutes)
Peak Hour
Base*
25.0
35.0
25.0
30.0
20.0
15.0
50.0
25.0
35.0
30.0
15.0
30.0
20.0
20.0
20.0
20.0
20.0
20.0
30.0
50.0
30.0
30.0
30.0
30.0
30.0
30.0
30.0
15.0
60.0
15.0
30.0
99.9
Plang
12.5
17.5
12.5
15.0
10.0
7.5
25.0
12.5
17.5
15.0
7.5
30.0
8.0
6.0
5.0
4.0
10.0
7.0
15.0
50.0
15.0
30.0
30.0
30.0
30.0
30.0
30.0
7.5
60.0
7.5
15.0
99.9
Midday
Base*
25.0
25.0
25.0
30.0
40.0
30.0
40.0
20.0
45.0
30.0
30.0
50.0
40.0
40.0
40.0
40.0
40.0
40.0
60.0
50.0
50.0
40.0
60.0
30.0
30.0
40.0
30.0
60.0
60.0
30.0
50.0
99.9
Plan@
12.5
12.5
12.5
15.0
20.0
15.0
20.0
10.0
22.5
15.0
15.0
50.0
15.0
15.0
15.0
15.0
15.0
15.0
30.0
50.0
25.0
40.0
60.0
30.0
30.0
40.0
30.0
30.0
60.0
15.0
25.0
99.5
*Base condition headways were obtained from 1975 transit system
 computer listing provided by CPO.

@Plan condition headways were derived by FMM&Co. and discussed
 with SDTC.

Note:  (1) Routes E-l, E-2, and S, which are relatively short
           routes, are onitted from the above listing.

       (2) Headways shown are generally the lowest headways
           on each bus route as coded in the transit networks.
                             25

-------
     Implementation of all of the schedule and route changes suggested
by the SDTC personnel would require full utiliEation of the 200 additional
buses to be purchased.  If it were desired to add many new bus routes in
the San Diego region—particularly to non-CBD destinations—it would appear
that more than 200 buses would have to be added to the bus fleet.

Methodology for Analyzing Impact of the EPA Promulgated Plan

     The methodology utilized in this study was based on regional
transportation data obtained from the San Diego Comprehensive Planning
Organization.  Certain refinements were required to more fully consider
the impacts of the EPA promulgated plan.  These refinements included:
(1)  an analysis of car-pooling impacts, and (2) a more thorough consid-
eration of foregone trips (i.e., those trips which will not be made because
of increased travel cost).  Significant revision of the regional modal
split model computer program was required in order to implement these
refinements of the original transportation planning data base.

     Utilization of the Regional Transportation Planning Process

     An overview of the transportation planning process of the San Diego
region is presented in Exhibit 1.  This exhibit illustrates each of
the six major phases of a strategic planning process, and the major
intermediate products which result from each phase of the analysis.

     The analyses described in this report were based on the fourth
step in the regional transportation planning process — the modal
split analysis.  Essentially, the modal split analysis estimates the
share of the urban travel market which is captured by each of the
major modes — where the modes are defined as transit passenger, auto-
mobile driver, and automobile passenger.  The modal split model is
predicated on the assumption that the market shares held by each mode
are a function of the level of service provided by each of the modes
(e.g. , price, travel time for different trip components including
walking, waiting, line-haul, and transfer) and the socioeconomic char-
acteristics of the traveler (e.g., income).  The major inputs to the modal
split analysis are:

     .  matrices of person trips by purpose between all
        zones of the San Diego region for the forecast year;

        a set of matrices describing the highway and transit
        travel times for each component of a trip between all
        zones in the San Diego region for the forecast year; and

        the household income distribution of the urban travelers
        for each traffic analysis zone.

     The major data inputs for the modal split process were provided by
CPO and modified as necessary for use in this analysis.  CPO also pro-
vided trip tables for total trips for a 1975 forecast year; as described
below, these were modified to develop trip tables for a 1977 forecast
year.

                                  26

-------
                     EXHIBIT 1.
OVERVIEW OF TRANSPORTATION PLANNING  PROCESS
              FOR SAN DIEGO REGION
                LAND USE FORECASTING
                  TRIP GENERATION
                                             POPULATION
                                                AND
                                             EMPLOYMENT
                                            SUMMARIES BY
                                                ZONE
                  TRIP DISTRIBUTION
                   MODAL SPLIT
               HIGHWAY AND TRANSIT
               NETWORK ASSIGNMENT
                                              TRIP TABLES
                                                FOR
                                             AUTO DRIVER,
                                          AUTO PASSENGER,
                                                AND
                                               TRANSIT
                                              PASSENGER
                SYSTEM EVALUATION
                                              HIGHWAY
                                               AND
                                          TRANSIT NETWORK
                                            LINK VOLUMES
                        27

-------
     The inputs made to the 1975 highway and transit systems in order
to describe  (1) the base system which would have existed in the San
Diego region prior to the advent of the EPA transporation control plan
and  (2) the transportation system which would result from implementation
of the EPA promulgated transportation control plan, have been described
above.

     Description of the Modal Split Model

     The modal split model is briefly described below.  A further
description of the structure, estimated parameters, and testing and
validation of the modal split model is presented in Appendix A. •*•

     For purposes of the modal split analysis, travel in the San Diego
region is stratified into two sets:  travel to CBD destinations, and
travel to non-CBD destinations.  This stratification was selected because
investigations indicated that the propensity to use transit for CBD travel
was  greater for equivalent service alternatives than it was for non-CBD
travel.

     A detailed analysis was undertaken to select  that  set of  independent
variables, and to estimate the best parameters for each of the  independent
variables that provide the highest quality modal split model for each  travel
stratification for the San Diego region.  Table 2 presents the  recommended
CBD  and non-CBD models.  Three transportation variables, the differences in
line-haul time, excess time, and modal costs, and  one socioeconomic variable
(i.e., household income) are used in the models.  All of the coefficients in
the  model are significant at the 95 percent level.


     The major contrast between the CBD and non-CBD models is to be
found in the time and cost coefficients:  C, D, and E.  For the CBD
medel, the effect of excess time as compared to line-haul time  (i.e. ,
ratio of £)  is about 1.63.  The derived value of time (i.e., the ratio
of E to C or D) is $3.18 per hour for line-haul time and $5.17 per hour
for  excess time.  These estimates confirm results observed elsewhere.
Excess time becomes a critical determinate of modal choice for non-CBD
trips as shown by the value of the coefficient C and the weight of excess
time (relative to line-haul time), both of which are substantially higher
than in the CBD model.  The increase in the weight of excess time from
1.6  to 6.8 affects both the major differences in CBD and non-CBD transit
service and the differences in travel behavior resulting therefrom.
    Implementation of the n-Dimensional Logit Model, Final Report
Prepared by Peat, Marwick, Mitchell & Co., Washington,  D.C.,  for the Compre-
hensive Planning Organization, San Diego County; California,  May 1972.
                                  28

-------
                                                        TABLE 2

                                              SAN DIEGO MODAL SPLIT MODELS

        Model Form;                                                         Parameters of the Models;

                                                                     Parameter    CBD model    Non-CBD model

         P = 1.0 + exp(aTI35 + b) + exp(cDX3 + dDL3 + eDCH + f)          °          0.0295         0.0268

                                  , T-nc 4. KN                            b         -1.4809        -0.5441
        p  _ 	exp (aT 13 5 + b)	
         D   1.0 + exp(aTI35 + b) + exp(cDX3 + dDL3 + eDCH + f)          c          0.0916         0.1314

           	exp (cDX3 + dDL3 + eDCH +  f	          d          0.0563         0.0192
        PT   1.0 + exp(aT135 + b) + exp(cDX3 + dDL3 + eDCH + £)
                                                                         e          0.0106         0.0184
                                                                         f          1.1635         1.6600
N>
VO
        Nomenclature;
        Pp> PD» PT = auto passenger, auto driver, and transit passenger modal choice probabilities

        exp        = exponential operator

        a, b, d,   = calibrated coefficients and constants  for the model
        d, e, f

        TI35       = transformed household ijicome
                   = 100/L-exp  (-0.035*INC1/

        INC =      = household  income  in hundreds of dollars

        DX3        = difference in excess time
                   = walk to/from auto time -  (walk to  transit time +  first wait  for transit + walk from transit)

        DL3        = difference in line haul time
                   - auto driving time -  (transit in vehicle time + transit transfer time)

        DCH        = difference in modal cost
                     auto operating  cost  (5
-------
     The models were tested to see if they could reproduce the total
number of automobile passenger, automobile driver, and transit passen-
gers trips in the calibration sample.  The CBD and non-CBD models
reproduced almost exactly the total number of trips by each of the three
modes considered.  Calculated trips were within a (negligible) fraction
of one percent of the observed trips.

     The models also reproduce the observed trip distributions by trip
length.  Cumulative distributions of transit trips as a function of trip
length (in minutes) as observed in the calibration data set and estimated
by model are presented in Figure A-3 of Appendix A.  In all trip length
ranges, the calculated distribution of transit passengers is within
about 15 percent or less of the observed distributions.  The accuracy
of these results is indicative of the overall quality of the models.

     Modifications to Develop Analysis for 1977 Forecast Year

     The data inputs provided by CPO were predicated on an analysis year
of 1975.  Inasmuch as the transportation control plan promulgated by EPA
was to achieve its full effect by July 1, 1977, it was necessary to develop
a 1977 analysis capability.  The modifications of the 1975 highway and
transit networks to develop networks which represent (1) the base system
which would exist in San Diego in 1977 prior to the advent of the EPA pro-
mulgated transportation control plan, and (2) the transportation system
which would exist as a consequence of the EPA promulgated transportation
control plan, have been described above.  Modifications of the 1975 trip
tables of total person trips to produce 1977 trip tables are described
below.

     Over the last .ten years, the best available estimates are that the
vehicle-miles of travel (VMT) by automobile in the San Diego region have
increased at a compounded annual growth rate of 5.5 percent.  This increase
in automobile travel has resulted from (1) increases in the total number
of trips caused by increased population and increased income, and improve-
ments to the highway system, and (2) increases in the average trip length
resulting from increases in income and improvements to the highway system.
The growth in annual VMT is a reasonable indicator of travel growth,
because over 98 percent of all trips are made by automobile in the San Diego
area.  Hence, each entry in the 1975 trip table was multiplied by a factor
of 1.12, thereby, ensuring that the total VMT increased at a rate of 5.5
percent per year under the base condition.

     In view of the relatively short two-year time frame for which this
extrapolation was accomplished, and the scope of this study, this approach
was considered acceptable.  If the analysis were to be accomplished for a
more extended time frame—beyond five to 10 years—it would be desireable
to proceed through the various phases of the transportation planning process
to ensure that the forecasts of total trips appropriately reflected differ-
ential changes in land use, trip generation, distribution, and the
major variables.
                                    30

-------
     The EPA promulgated transportation control plan provides major
incentives for car-pooling and significantly increases the out-of-pocket
cost of an automobile trip (as a result of the parking surcharge) which
may result in certain trips no longer being undertaken.  These aspects
of the EPA promulgated plan are of such significance that modifications
of the previously developed modal split process were undertaken to ensure
that these impacts were appropriately assessed; these modifications are
described below.

     Analysis of Car-Pooling Impacts and Surcharges

     Because of the major pricing incentives created by the EPA plan to
encourage car-pooling, it was necessary to develop a more explicit mechan-
ism for assessing the impacts upon automboile occupancy.  An assessment of
the total cost per person of using an automobile for home-work travel in
1977 under the EPA promulgated transportation plan for various levels of
automobile occupancy is presented in Table 3.  In considering the costs
for automobile travel, it was useful to distinguish between non-CBD oriented
travel—which largely involves employer provision for free parking facilities—
and CBD oriented travel—which largely requires employees to utilize commer-
cial parking facilities.  In considering the non-CBD oriented travel, it is
further useful to distinguish betwen employees working for employers with
more than 100 employees and employees working for employers with fewer than
100 employees inasmuch as the surcharge program differs for these two groups
of employees.  This distinction is not relevant in the case of CBD oriented
travel,  since the surcharge for commercial parking facilities is imposed
upon employees irrespective of the size of the organization by which they
are employed.

     The total one-way driving cost and the average one-way cost per person
for each of these travel groups, assuming automobile occupancies of 1, 2,
and 3 persons, are presented in Table A.  The average travel distances for
home-to-work travelers with CBD and non-CBD destinations were those observed
in the 1966 home interview survey.  While the average travel distances for
home-to-work travel in 1977 are greater than they were in 1966, the increases
in average trip distance do not significantly affect the results.

     In conducting the analysis, a major effort was made to identify data
pertaining to car-pooling arrangements in San Diego or elsewhere in the
country to assess the increases in average travel distance and average travel
time associated with car pools of two and three individuals.  Unfortunately,
it was not possible to locate any survey data pertaining to the incremental
travel times and travel distances associated with car pooling.  The impedances
associated with car pooling were therefore based on the following assumptions:

        for trip interchanges involving 100 or more trips, the
        incremental travel time associated with one added passenger
        in the car is five minutes for the driver, and the incre-
        mental travel time associated with two passengers in the car
        is eight minutes for the driver and three minutes for the
        second passenger—this is the total incremental time for the
        trip and considers the added travel time for both the origin
        and the destination;

-------
                                      TABLE 3

                        IMPACTS OF CAR POOLING UPON COSTS OF
                    HOME-WORK AUTOMOBILE TRAVEL IN 1977 UNDER EPA
                       PROMULGATED TRANSPORTATION CONTROL PLAN

Non-CBD Oriented Travel -
Free Parking Facilities
Employees working for Employers with
greater than 100 employees
Average one-way travel distance (miles)
Out-of-pocket distance cost (cents)*
Parking cost (cents)*
Total one-way trip cost (cents)*
Average one-way trip cost per person (cents)*
Incremental charge in one-way trip cost
per person (cents)*
Incremental travel time (minutes)
Employees working for employers with
less than 100 employees
Average one-way travel distance (miles)
Out-of-pocket distance cost (cents)*
Parking cost (cents )*
Total one-way trip cost (cents)*
Average one-way trip cost per person (cents)*
Incremental charge in one-way trip cost
per person (cents)*
Incremental travel time (minutes)
CDB Oriented Travel - Commercial
Parking Facilities
All Employees
Average one-way travel distance (miles)
Out-of-pocket distance cost (cents)*
Parking cost (cents)*
Total one-way trip cost (cents)*
Average one-way trip cost per person (cents)*
Incremental charge in one-way trip cost
per person (cents)*
Incremental travel time (minutes)
Number of Persons in Car Pool
1




7.1
63.4
125.0
188.4
188.4

-
-


7.1
63.4
125.0
188.4
188.4

-
-



7.7
68.8
163.1
231.9
231.9

-
-
2




9.3
83.0
62.5
145.5
77.8

115.6
6.5


9.3
83.0
125.0
208.0
104.0

84.4
6.5



9.9
88.4
163.1
251.5
125.8

106.1
6.5
3




10.5
93.8
0.0
93.8
31.3

41.5
3.9


10.5
93.8
125.0
218.8
72.9

31.1
3.9



11.1
99.1
163.1
262.2
87.4

38.4
3.9
*1977 prices, 1972-3 base.
                                      32

-------
                                     TABLE 4

                         CAR POOLING PARTICIPATION RATES
    Income Level
Income between 0
and $5,000 per year

   Proportion of car
   pools with this
   occupancy

   Proportion of persons
   with this occupany

Income between $5,000
and $10,000 per year

   Proportion of car
   pools with this
   occupancy

   Proportion of persons
   with this occupancy

Income greater than
$10,000 per year

   Proportion of car
   pools with this
   occupancy

   Proportion of persons
   with this occupancy
Number of Passengers  in Automobile

       123
      .09
      .24
               .3
.26
               .5
.59
      .43
               .4
.57
         .5
.65
         .1
.17
         .0
.0
                                                                 Average Auto-
                                                                mobile Occupancy
                                           2.3
                                           1.7
                                           1.4
                                      33

-------
        the automobile driver will achieve an average speed of
        20 mph in picking up and dropping off passengers at each
        end of the trip; and

        corresponding incremental travel times and travel dis-
        tances for interchanges involving fewer than 100 trips
        are 130 percent of the corresponding values for inter-
        changes involving more than 100 trips.

About 85 percent of the home-to-work travel in San Diego involves inter-
changes with fewer than 100 trips; thus, most of the home-to-work trav-
elers are assumed to have incremental times of 6.5 and 10.4 minutes and
incremental distances of 2.2 and 3.4 miles for automobile occupancies
of two and three respectively.  The incremental times and distances for
each number of persons in a car pool are summarized in Table 5.

     A conclusion that can be drawn is that travelers achieve substantial
savings—on the order of $.84 to $1.50 per one-way trip—by increasing the
automobile occupancy from one to two persons.  The incremental savings,
which is achieved by increasing the automobile occupancy from two persons
to three persons is relatively speaking smaller—ranging from about $.31
to $.42 for each one-way trip.

     These resutls suggest two findings regarding traveler behavior in
response to the pricing incentives to car pool.  First, those travelers
with a lower income will have a greater incentive to car pool than those
travelers with a higher income—all other factors being equal.  Thus, the
rate of automobile occupancy might be expected to decreases as the trav-
eler's income increase.  Second, the incremental savings which are to
be derived by increasing automobile occupancy from one to two persons is
about 2.7 times greater than the incremental savings which are derived by
increasing the automobile occupancy from two to three persons.  In this
context, two-person car pools might be expected to offer significant
attractions to travelers in spite of the fact that ever greater savings
are provided by three-person car pools.

     The relatively high average automobile occurancy rates of 2.3, 1.7,
and 1.4 persons for the low, medium5 and high income ranges may be con-
trasted with the base period average automobile occupancy for home-to-
work travel of 1.1 to 1.2 persons per automobile.  Given these car-pooling
participation rates, over half of the persons with low incomes would travel
to work in three-passenger car pools, whereas over half of the persons with
medium and high incomes would travel to work in two-passenger car pools.
In contrast, about 82 percent of the persons in the base condition traveled
to work in automobiles in which they were the only occupant.

     The car-pooling participation rates for different income groups as
well as the incremental impedances associated with car-pooling were utilized
to analyze the car-pooling impacts of the transportation control plan.  Inas-
much as the base plan involved incremental improvements of the existing system
with no major pricing incentive to encourage car-pooling, the automobile
occupancy analysis incorporated into the calibrated modal split model for the
San Diego region (as described above.) was utilized in this analysis.


                                  34

-------
                                TABLE 5

                    INCREMENTAL TIMES AND DISTANCES
Interchange
involves 100
or more trips

Interchange
involves fewer
than 100 trips
                    Travel Time
                   No. of Persons
                   in Automobile

                    2         3
                (minutes) (minutes)
6.5
10.4
                   Travel Distance
                   No.  of Persons
                   in Automobile

                      2       3
                   (miles) (miles)
                     1.7
2.2
                    2.6
3.4
                              Proportion of
                             Total Work Trips
                             in this Category

                                 Percent
                      15.0
85.0
                                 35

-------
     Consideration of Foregone Trips

     It was recognized at the outset of this study that the combination
of an enhanced level of public transportation in the San Diego region as
well as restrictions imposed upon automobile usage might affect the number
of trips undertaken in the region as well as their destinations.  The
difficulty of reliably estimating induced or foregone trips was also
recognized; aside from the nodal split model, the existing travel demand
analysis for the San Diego region is not sensitive to the costs of auto-
mobile travel nor to the level of service provided by the transit system.
Thus, while the importance of carefully assessing induced and foregone
trips was recognized, it was also understood that the results of such an
analysis are more open to question than the results of the modal split
analysis.

     The parking surcharge measure promulgated in the transportation
control plan significantly increased the out-of-pocket cost of automobile
travel for essentially all work and non-work trips undertaken in the
region.  These increases in the cost of automobile travel are so great that
they would undoubtedly motivate changes in the frequency and destinations
of automobile travel, in addition to encouraging automobile users to divert
to transit.  If the impacts of the increases in automobile costs upon the
frequency and destinations of trips were not consdiered, the results of this
analysis vrould be highly unrealistic.  It was, therefore, imperative that
some mechanism be incorporated into the analysis for assessing the extent
to which trips would be foregone as a result of the automobile price in-
creases.

     The increase in the bus fleet from the planned 350 buses under the
base condition to a total of 550 buses represents a most important 57 per-
cent increase in the size of the bus fleet relative to the base condition
for 1977 and is about 220 percent greater than the existing 1973 fleet of
250 buses.  While this represents a most significant improvement to the
regional bus service, it should be recognized that the parking surcharge
represents a greater potential impact on the total regional transportation
service than does this increase in the number of buses.  In this context,
it was evident that the analysis of induced and foregone trips needed to
focus primarily upon the impacts of the parking surcharge and secondarily
upon the impacts of the bus service improvements.  While an assessment of
the induced travel demands resulting from the recent transit fare reductions
in San Diego and Atlanta provides some insight into the induced demands
resulting from improved bus service, these results do not provide sufficient
information to assess the impacts of increases in the out-of-pocket cost of
automobile travel upon automobile users.  A literature review was therefore
undertaken to identify and assess the existing models for assessing the
travel consumption affects of the automobile price increases.

     The literature review identified five approaches for achieving this
objective:

     .  Demand Generator and Modal Split Model—Rand Corp.;


                                 36

-------
     .  Direct Demand Estimation Model—Kraft;

     .  Attitudinal Model—Wallace;

        Shopping Trip Frequency Model—Charles River Associates;
        and

        Econometric Model of Gasoline Consumption—Data Resources, Inc.

A description and assessment of each of these approaches is presented in
Appendix B.

     It was concluded that the Econometric Model of Gasoline Consumption
provides, at this time, the most reliable available method for assessing
the impacts of the increases in the price of automobile usage upon the
consumption of person-miles of travel.  The approach taken by Rand—while
conceptually interesting—was rejected because the relationship postulated
in the report did not appear to have been empirically calibrated or valid-
ated to a sufficient extent.  The Direct Demand Estimation Model suggested
by Kraft and a number of other authors is  also conceptually attrative but
it has proven extremely difficult to calibrate and validate reliable dir-
ect demand estimation models using aggregate data.  The Attitudinal Models,
such as those suggested by Wallace, differ from the other approaches in
that they are based upon ellicited attitudes rather than actual travel
behavior.  While the approach appears to offer promise, fully developed
models of this type have yet to be implemented in a form such that they
can be used in this study.  The Shopping Trip Frequency Model developed
by Charles River Associates is a most useful development—particularly
because it is  feasible to calibrate this model using a disaggregate
approach.  The work is insufficiently developed, however, for use at this
time in this sutdy for two reasons:  (1)  corresponding models have not
been developed for the other trip purposes, and (2) while the model
addresses the issue of trip frequency, it does not allow for consideration
of changes in trip destination.

     The Econometric Model of Gasoline Consumption developed by Data
Resources, Inc. has been empirically validated and directly addresses the
issue of changes in the vehicle-miles of travel; for these reasons, it
was selected for use in this study.

     The basic assumption underlying the use of the results of this econ-
ometric model of the quarterly demand for gasoline as a function of gasoline
price and income is that the price elasticities estimated for gasoline con-
sumption could also be used as estimates of the price elasticities for
consumption of vehicle-miles of travel (and thus, person-miles of travel
assuming constant automobile occupance and relatively minor diversion to
transit).  Factors to be considered in assessing the reasonableness of
this approach include:
                                  37

-------
      .   the price of gasoline represented  essentially  a  constant
         proportion of the total out-of-pocket  costs  of automobile
         travel during the time period  represented by the calibration
         data;

         changes in gasoline consumption may have resulted from
         changes other than vehicle-miles of travel (e.g., substi-
         tution of automobiles which  provide a  greater  number of
         miles  per gallon);  and

      .   changes in travel patterns are "appropriately" related to
         the changes in gasoline consumption.

 A review of available information    regarding  the per-mile costs of
 operating a car suggests  that during the period covered  by the cali-
 bration data set for the model,  the  cost of gasoline has constituted
 essentially a  constant proportion of the costs of operating a car.

     Admittedly,  gasoline  consumption  is being used  in this analysis as
 a surrogate for vehicle-miles of travel.   If the average miles per gallon
 achieved by automobiles increase or  decrease,  the vehicle miles of travel
 would correspondingly increase or decrease with no change in gasoline con-
 sumption.   Changing one's consumption  of vehicle-miles of travel is,
 however,  an immediately feasible action which  consumers  can take in res-
 ponse to  changes  in gasoline  prices.   Other changes—such as the substi-
 tution  of  automobiles  which achieve  a  higher gas mileage—require a longer
 time to achieve.  The  Econometric Model of Gasoline Demand provides both
 a  short-run price elasticity  (which  is defined as the  elasticity for the
 immediate  three months  following the price change),  and  a long-run price
 elasticity  (which is defined  as the  elasticity pertaining to a period
 approximately 10 quarters following  a  price change).    In this context,
 the short-run elasticity may  be viewed as a conservative estimate of the
 change  in vehicle miles of travel.   For this reason,  the estimate of short-
 run elasticity  of gasoline demands was utilized in this  study to estimate
 foregone  trips  as a function  of increased travel costs.

     The analysis of  the demand for  gasoline was conducted with four
 different data  sets, each of which measured a  slightly different version
 of the  aggregate  sales  of gasoline.  Of these  four data  sets for gasoline
 consumption, the "Federal Highway Administration's Highway Motor Fuel
 less Highway Special Fuels" estimate of gasoline consumption pertained
most closely to an  estimate of the gasoline consumed  for highway driving.
 Thus, the short-run price elasticity for gasoline consumption based on
 this data which has a value of -.16 using an error component estimation
 technique with  a linear model  — was utilized  in this  study.  The short-
 run price elasticities for gasoline  consumption which were estimated using
 the other three data sources were comparable,  although somewhat lower,
 than this estimate.                              -
   The Cost of Operating An Automobile, Federal Highway Administration,
   Washington, B.C., published periodically.
                                  38

-------
     This estimate of -.16 for the short-run price elasticity was
developed using consumption data for all states.   Prior to utilizing
such an estimate, it is necessary to consider whether it is applicable
to the case study city — San Diego.  While it was not possible to
validate this model utilizing data from San Diego, the model has been
validated using California data.  Examination of  the actual versus the
estimated values for California suggested that the utilization of this
parameter for California did not cause significant errors in prediction
of gasoline consumption.  The simple correlation  coefficient when com-
paring predicted and actual values of gasoline consumption for California
using the "Federal Highway Administration Highway Motor Fuel less Special
Fuel" data base was .996.

     One further modification of this elasticity  was required in order
that it be specified on a basis comparable to its use in this study.  It
appears reasonable to assume that within the range of price changes caused
by the transportation control plan, travelers would not change their con-
sumption of home-to-work travel — except in the  most marginal and stat-
istically insignificant employment situations. The work trip will be one
of the last trips to be foregone, since this would imply that the house-
hold is also foregoing its income.  Since the surcharge program would be
applied essentially uniformly throughout the San  Diego region, there
would also be no incentive for workers to shift employment sites in order
to alleviate the economic effect of the parking surcharge, except in those
instances where transit service would serve one job location but not another.
Thus, within the price range of the increase in automobile costs resulting
from the parking surcharge, it appears reasonable as a first order of
approximation to assume that all of the changes in travel consumption
would be for non-work travel.  Inasmuch as the price changes for gasoline
during the period represented by the calibration  data set for the Econo-
metric Model were also relatively minor, a comparable assumption could be
made that the changes pertain solely to the changes in travel consumption
for non-work purposes.  Inasmuch as the short-run elasticity estimated by
the model considers gasoline consumption for all  trip purposes — both work
and non-work — one could argue that this average elasticity overestimates
the short-run elasticity of travel consumption for work travel and under-
estimates the short-run elasticity of consumption for non-work travel.  The
travel analyses indicate that in the 1975-1977 time frame, about 52.9 percent
of the travel in the region is non-work related and the remaining 47.1
percent is work related.  Given the previous assumptions that consumption
of work travel is essentially inelastic and the estimate of the proportion
of travel which is non-work, it can be seen that  the short-run price elas-
ticity of non-work travel is -.16 divided by .5294 or -.302.  This estimate
of the short-run price elasticity of travel was utilized in this analysis.

     Finally, it is necessary to consider the range of validity for this
elasticity estimate.  In discussions with the model developers, it was
suggested that the elasticity estimates were valid for gasoline prices
up to 60 cents per gallon — a 50 percent price increase as compared to
the early 1973 price or 40 cents per gallon.  Consequently, it was assumed
that the elasticity estimate was valid for up to  a 50 percent increase in


                                   39

-------
the out-of-pocket costs of automobile travel.  Inasmuch as the parking
costs (including the surcharge) are constant irrespective of the length
of the trip and the other out-of-pocket costs increase with the average
trip length, the relative increase in the total out-of-pocket cost repre-
sented by the parking surcharge decreases with increasing trip distance.
Assuming a parking duration of 1.6 hours or less for all non-work travel,
it was found that the relative increase in the out-of-pocket cost of
automobile travel exceeded 50 percent for trip lengths less than 3.5
miles.  The anlaysis was therefore predicated on the conservative
assumption that the relative increase in price for trips less than 3.5
miles was no more than 50 percent; and that for trip lengths greater
than 3.5 miles, the relative increase in the out-of-pocket costs was
correspondingly small.

     Implementation of the Analysis Refinements

     The computer code previously developed to apply the regional modal
split model was modified to incorporate the following:

        stratify home-to-work trips by income category and according
        to whether they work for employers with more than 100 em-
        ployees or employers with fewer than 100 employees;

        apply the appropriate car-pool participation rate to each
        stratification;

        compute the appropriate automobile and transit impedances for
        the workers in each category (these impedances vary according
        to car-pool size, whether the organization employed more than
        or fewer than 100 employees, and whether commercial parking
        facilities were available in the zone);

        apply the modal split model to each segment of home-to-work
        travel to estimate transit usage and then appropriately
        compute the number of automobile users;

        estimate the number of foregone trips using the price
        elasticity of travel applied to non-work trips;

        estimate the modal split of non-work trips using the non-
        work modal split factors after reducing total non-work
        trips by the number of trips foregone;

        estimate the modal split of foregone non-work trips
        using the* non-work modal split factors added to other
        non-work transit trips; and

        output the work and non-work travel patterns, trips
        foregone, and transportation system characteristics data
        in a form suitable for use in the evaluation process.
                                  40

-------
RESULTS OF THE TRANSPORTATION ANALYSIS

     A discussions of the findings of this analysis with respect  to  the
impacts of the EPA promulgated transportation control plan upon travel
behavior and the transportation system in the San Diego  region  is pre-
sented in this section.  This discussion focuses  upon the total impacts
at a regional scale, on the incidence of the impacts with respect to
household incomes, and on the geographic incidence of the impacts.   A
detailed description of the results for both the  base and the plan sys-
tems—stratified with respect to trip purpose and geographic and  house-
hold income incidence—is presented in Appendix C.

     Impacts of the transportation control plan are measured in terms of
the following criteria:

     . person trips—the average number of trips  which residents
       of the San Diego region would undertake on an average work
       day in mid-1977;

     . person miles—the total miles of travel which residents  of
       the San Diego region would undertake on an average work  day
       in mid-1977, the person miles of travel for automobile
       drivers is the vehicle-miles of travel (VMT);

     . travel costs—the total daily cost of travel expressed in
       1973 dollars which residents of the San Diego region would
       pay on an average work day in mid-1977; and

     . travel time—the total daily hours associated with the
       travel of residents of the San Diego region in mid-1977.

Distribution of the out-of-pocket costs and travel time  associated with
individual automobile and transit trips under the base and plan conditions
are also presented.

Impacts at a Regional Scale

     The impacts of the transportation control plan upon the San  Diego
region—as measured by changes in the above identified four criteria—
are presented in Table 6.  The major findings which can  be developed from
this exhibit are:

     . whereas the volume of automobile driver trips decreases  by
       about 18 percent, the VMT decreases by only about 12 percent;

     . the factors contributing to the reduction.in VMT  in order  of
       decreasing importance;
                                  41  ..

-------
                                                                                   TABLE 6
                                                             Regional Impacts of the Transportation Control Plan
Dally Person Trips
Daily Person Miles
Daily Travel Cost
(100' a of 1973
dollars)
Daily Travel Time
•(hours) ,
Transit
Base
130,000
459,000
200
68,000
Plan
204,000
678,000
400
110,000
Percent of
Difference
57.1
47.8
61.9
62.5
Automobile Driver
; Base
3,563,000
24,786,000
Plan
2,912,000
21,716,000,
Percent of
Difference
-18.3
-12.4
Automobile Passenger
Base
1,288,000
8,866,000
Plan
1,524,000
11,380,000
Percent of
Difference
18.1
28.4
Total For Auto Person
21,000
1,170,000
48,000
1,165,000
132.8
-.4
-
Total
Base
4,980,000
34,111,000
21,000
1,238,000
Plan
4,637,000
33,773,000.
48,000
1,276,000
Percent of
Difference
-6.9
-1.0
131.9
3.1
N>

-------
     • increases in carpooling transportation rates
     r trips being foregone

     . diversion of automobile travel to transit travel

     . the cost of daily travel in the San Diego region  increases
       by about 132 percent at the same time as  the  number  of trips
       and person-miles of travel are decreasing by  about 7 and
       1 percent respectively; and

     . the total travel time for the San Diego region marginally
       increases—about 3 percent—although person trips and person-
       miles of travel are decreasing.

     An understanding of why a reduction of about 18 percent in the
number of trips results in a reduction of only about 12  percent in the
VMT can be developed from a consideration of the average trip lengths
for automobile driver trips (see Table 7.)  Because  of the  additional
travel distance required to pick-up and drop-off the carpool passengers,
the average trip length for an automobile driver work trip  is 11 percent
greater under the plan condition than under the  base condition.  The
average trip length for non-work trips also increases under the plan
condition but for a different reason.  The relative  increase in the cost
of an automobile trip resulting from the parking surcharge  decreases  as
the length of the trip increases and for this reason, it might be
expected that the relative proportion of shorter trips which would be
foregone would be greater than the relative proportion of longer trips
which would be foregone.  Thus, it is not surprising that the average
trip length for the foregone trips is about 6.3  miles as compared to  an
average trip length under the base condition for all non-work trips of
6.8 miles.  Thus, the average trip length for those  non-work automobile
trips which are not foregone is longer than the  corresponding trip
length under the base condition.  Inasmuch as the average trip length
for those trips which continue to be made increases, the VMT reduction
resulting from the 1870 reduction in the volume of trips  is  smaller than
might have otherwise been expected.

     An assessment of the factors resulting in the reductions in auto-
mobile travel is presented in Table 8.  The diversion of the automobile
driver trip to a carpool represents the single largest cause of the re-
duction in automobile travel—as defined in terms of both person trips
and VMI.  Because of the increase in automobile  travel distance asso-
ciated with carpooling, this factor has a greater influence upon the
reduction in person trips than it does on the relative reduction of
VMT.  The foregoing of the trip entirely is the  second largest factor
influencing the reduction in automobile travel.   Whereas only about
35 percent of the reduction in person trips were -foregone trips, about
46 percent of the reduction in VMT were foregone trips.  Finally,
transit accounted for about 7 percent of the reduction in automobile
                                  43

-------
        TABLE 7

AVERAGE TRIP LENGTH FOR
   AUTOMOBILE TRIPS

Work Trips
Non Work Trips
Total Trips
Foregone Trips
Base
(Miles)
7.14
6.81
6.96

Plan
(Miles)
7.93
7.13
7.46
6.27
Percent
Difference
11.1
4.7
7.2
-
         44

-------
            TABLE 8




REDUCTION IN AUTOMOBILE TRAVEL

FACTORS
CAUSING
REDUCTION
IN AUTOMOBILE
TRAVEL
Trip Foregone
Trip diverted to
transit
Trip diverted to
car pool
Total
AUTOMOBILE
DRIVER
TRIPS
NUMBER
227,000
48,700
-374,900
650,600
PERCENT
OF TOTAL
REDUCTION
34.9
7.5
57.6
100.0
VEHICLE
MILES
NUMBER
1,423,000
144,000
1,504,000
3,071,000
PERCENT
OF TOTAL
REDUCTION
46.3
4.7
49.0
100.0
             45'

-------
driver trips and about 5 percent of the reduction in VMT.  The  average
transit trip length is only about 3.3 miles—less than half  of  the
average trip length for automobile trips.

     Although the volume of trips decreases  by about 7 percent  and  the
person miles of travel decreases by about  1  percent, the  total  travel
costs for residents of the San Diego Region  increases by  about  132  percent
under the plan condition.  This cost increase  is  largely  a result of
the parking surcharge.  As might be expected,  the relative increase in
the transit cost is essentially the same as  the relative  increase in
the number of transit trips.  It should be recognized that the  cost
increase for automobile occurs in spite of the fact  that  the number of
trips decreases by about 7 percent, and the  number of person-miles
decreases by about 1 percent.

     The total travel time for residents of  the San  Diego region
increases by about 3 percent under the plan  condition. The  total travel
time for automobile passengers essentially remains constant, although
it should be recognized that the total number  of  automobile  trips will
decrease by approximately 417,000.  The total  travel time for transit
travelers increases in approximately the same  relative proportion as
the increase in the total number of transit  trips.

Incidence of the Impacts Upon Various Income Groups

     It was recognized at the outset of this study that although the
overall effects of the transportation control  plan might  be  acceptable,
the plan might have unacceptable impacts upon  specific subgroups of
residents of the San Diego region—as defined  in  terms of their incomes
and their geographical residence within the  region.   The  incidence  of
the impacts with respect to residents with different incomes are
summarized in Tables 9A through 9D.  Three income ranges  were util-
ized in this analysis representing low, medium, and  high  incomes, re-
spectively.  It should be recognized that  these income ranges are ex-
pressed in 1966 dollars and that they would  be about 26.5 percent
greater were they expressed in 1973 dollars.

     The relative decrease in the number of  automobile driver trips de-
creases as the household income increases  with a  maximum  decrease of
26 percent for the low income range and about  15  percent  for the high
income range.  This result is as might be  expected inasmuch  as  house-
holds with greater incomes would have a greater capacity  to  pay the
significantly increased costs of automobile  usage.  Similarly,  the
relative increase in the number of automobile  passengers  decreases  as
the household income increases from a high of  about  35 percent  for  the
low income range to a low of about 10 percent  for the high income
range.  In contrast, however, the relative increase  in the number of
transit trips increases as the household income increases from  a low
of about 14 percent for the lowest .income  range to a high of about
                                 46

-------
A •
           TABLE 9A

INCOME INCIDENCE OF  THE IMPACTS
         PERSON TRIPS
Household
Income
(1966 dollars)
0,000-4,999
5,000-9,999
10,000 +
Total
Transit
Base
22,000
62,000
46,000
130,000
Plan
25,000
97,000
82,000
204,000
Percent
Difference
13.6
56.5
78.4
57.1
Automobile Driver
Base
216,000
1,496,000
1,850,000
3,563,000
Plan
159,000
1,176,000
1,576,000
2,912,000
Percent
Difference
-26.3
• -21.4
-14.8
-18.3
Automobile Passenger
Base
83,000
547,000
658,000
1,288,000
Plan
112,000
683,000
726,000
1,521,000
Percent
Difference
34.9
24.9
10.4
18.1
Total
Base
321,000
2,105,000
2,554,000
4,980,000
Plan
296,000
1,956,000
2,385,000
4,637,000
Percent
Difference
-7.8
-7.1
-6.7
-6.9

-------
                                                                             TABLE 9B




                                                                            PERSON MILES
Household
Income
(1966 dollars)
0,000-4,999
5,000-9,999
10,000 +
Total
Transit
Base
67,000
211,000
181,000
459,000
Plan
67,000
309,000
301,000
678,000
Percent
Difference
1.0
46.8
66.2
47.8
Automobile Driver
Base
1,339,000
10,282,000
13,166,000
24,786,000
Plan
1,061,000
8,704,000
11,951,000
21,716,000
Percent
Difference
-20.8
-15.4
-9.2
-12.4
Automobile Pasoenger
Base
508,000
3,700,000
4,659,000'
8,866,000
• Plan
784,000
5,111,000
5,485,000
11,380,000
Percent
Difference
54.4
38.1
17.7
28.4
Total
Base
1,913,000
14,192,000
18,006,000
34,111,000
Plan
1,912,000
14,124,000
17,737,000
13,773,000
Percent
Hfference
-.1
-.5
-1.5
-1.0
00

-------
                                                                         TABLE  9C
                                                                       TRAVEL COST
                                                                        ($000, 1973)
Household
Income
(1966 dollars)
0,000-4,999
5,000-9,999
10,000 +
Total
Transit Automobile
Base
42
127
94
265
Plan
52
205
172
429
Percent
Difference
23.8
61.4
"83.0
61.9
Base
1,137
8,534
10,876
20,550
Plan
2,532
19,247
26,072
47,850
Percent
Difference
122.7
125.5
139.7
132.9
Total
Base
1,179
8,661
10,970
20,815
Plan
2,584
19,452
26,244
48,279
Percent
Difference
119.2
124.6
139.2
131.9
VD

-------
                                                                                TABLE  9D



                                                                               TRAVEL  TIME

                                                                                  (Hours)
Household
Income
(1966 Dollars)
0,000-4,999
5,000-9,999
10,000 +
Total
Transit
Base
10,000
31,000
26,000
68,000
Plan
12,000
51,000
47,000
110,000
Percent
Difference
15.9
61.6
82.1
62.5
Automobile
Base
66,000
488,000
616,000
1,170,000
Plan
68,000
490,000
608,000
1,165,000
Percent
Difference
2.1
.5
-1.3
- .4
Total
Base
77,000
519,000
642,000
1,238,000
Plan
80,000
541,000
655,000
1,276,000
Percent
Difference
4.0
4.2
2.0
3.1
1/1
o

-------
78 percent for the highest income range.  The relationship between auto-
mobile car pooling and transit usage is evident from these results;
essentially, the lower income travelers are tending to carpool relatively
more and use transit relatively less, whereas the higher  income travlers
are carpooling relatively less and using transit relatively more.

     The relative changes in the person-miles of travel essentially
correspond to the relative changes in the number of person trips.   For
each income group, the relative decrease in the VMT is less than the
corresponding relative decrease in the number of trips for that income
group.  Similarly, the increase in the person-miles of travel for  auto-
mobile passengers is relatively greater for each income group than the
corresponding increase in the number of automobile passengers—this is
a result of the increase in trip lengths which are required to suc-
cessfully accomplish carpooling.  For each income group,  the relative
increase in the person-miles of transit travel is less than the corres-
ponding increase in the number of transit trips; this suggests that the
trips which are diverted to transit have a relatively short trip length.
The relative increase in the travel costs increases with increasing
household income from a low of about 119 percent for the low income
group to a high of 139 percent for the high income group.  In a relative
sense, then, those residents with the greatest incomes have the greatest
relative increases in their travel costs.  On the other hand, the in-
creases in travel costs are so great that their absolute impact on
residents in all income ranges cannot be ignored.

     The relative increase in the total travel time for the low and
medium income groups is about 4 percent, whereas the relative increase
for the high income group is only about 2 percent.  This is probably a
consequence of the lower rate of carpooling which occurs among the high
income group.  Though the increase in total travel time is relatively
small—about 3 percent—it should be recognized that the total number
of trips has decreased by approximately 7 percent.

Geographic Incidence of the Impacts

     The San Diego region was subdivided into six major statistical
areas (MSAs) to assess the geographical incidence of the impacts.   A
map describing the MSAs is presented in Exhibit 2.  MSA 0 essential re-
presents the City of San Diego and certain close-in suburbs.  MSAs 1,
2, and 3 contain essentially all of the remaining suburbs of the City
of San Diego.  Portions of the MSAs 1 and 3 are located over 30 miles
from the central business district of the City of San Diego.  MSA 4
contains several urbanized areas which are in the North County and are
generally beyond commuting range from the CBD of San Diego.  Neither
San Diego Transit Corporation nor the Oceanside Transit System  operates
bus service from MSA 4 to MSA 0.  MSA 5 contains essentially undeveloped
desert and no transit service is available.
                                 51

-------
            EXHIBIT 2
SAN DIEGO MAJOR STATISTICAL AREAS
              52

-------
     The impacts of the transportation control plan with respect  to
each of the MSAs is presented in Tables 10A through 10D.   Essentially
all of the MSAs experience the same relative change in the number of
automobile driver and automobile passenger trips.   Two of the three
suburban MSAs—MSAs 1 and 3—experience a rate of  increase of transit
trips approximately twice that experienced by the  other MSAs. Overall,
however, residents of MSA 0 have the greatest number of transit trips
of any of the MSAs under both the base and the plan conditions.

     All of the MSAs experience approximately the  same relative decrease
in the VMT and the same relative increase in automobile passenger miles
of travel.  MSA 4 has the greatest relative^Jn the person-miles or"       $
transit travel reflecting longer average transit trip lengths.  Con-     \
sidering the total person-miles of travel as in auto transit  passenger,
in automobile driver, and in automobile passenger, it is interesting to
note residents of MSAs 0 and 1 experience decreases in their  person-
miles of about 19 and 13 percent, respectively, whereas the decreases
in the person-miles of travel in the other MSAs is essentially negli-
gible. Thus, the decrease in the person-miles of travel of residents of
the most densely settled portion of the San Diego  region is significantly
greater than the decrease for the residents of the less densely settled
portions.

     Considering the relative changes in the travel costs, it is  evident
that the greater the density of the area, the greater the relative  in-
crease in the travel costs of residents.  The central area—MSA 0—
experiences a relative increase in travel cost of  about 156 percent,
whereas the San Diego suburbs—MSA's 1, 2, and 3—experience  relative
increases of about"130 percent and the other MSA's experience even
smaller relative increases.  Thus, residents of MSA 0—essentially  the
City of San Diego and National City—experience the greatest  relative
increase in the travel costs at the same time as they are experiencing
the greatest relative decrease in the person-miles of travel.

     The relative change in the average travel time of trip of each MSA
is presented in Table 10E.  The average travel time for transit trips
is approximately twice the travel time for the automobile trips under
both the base and plan conditions.  The average travel times  for
residents of MSAs 0 and 2 increase about twice as  much as the times  for
residents of the other MSAs.

Travel Times and Travel Costs Per Trip

     The preceding discussion focused upon the total time and the total
costs for all of the trips in a category.  Thus, if the cost  per  trip
increased by 50 percent but the number of trips in that category
decreased by 33 1/3 percent, the total cost of travel would not change.
This section focuses upon the average travel time  and the average travel
cost per trip under the base and plan conditions.
                                 53

-------
                                                                              TABLE  IDA




                                                                            PERSON TRIPS
MSA
0
1
2
3
;A ,
'5 .
Total
Transit
Base
70,000
21,000
23,000
11,000
5,000
1 0
130,000
Plan
99,000
40,000
35,000
22,000
8,000
0
204,000
Percent
Difference
41.2
92.0
52.3
108.7
48.9
-
57.1
Automobile Driver
Base
1,051,000
889,000
353,000
645,000
624,000
200
3,563,000
Plan
847,000
734,000
285,000
532,000
514,000
200
2,912,000
Percent
Difference
-19.4
-17.4
-19.4
-17.5
-17.6
-9.2
-18.3
Automobile Passenger
Base
390,000
323,000
126,000
229,000
221,000
100
1.288.000
Plan
451,000
375,000
150,000
273,000
272,000
100
1.521,000
Percent
Difference
15.8
16.1
19.6
19.2
23.2
4".3
18.1
Total
Base
1,510,000
1,233,000
502,000
885,000
850,000
300
4.980,000
Plan
1,397,000
1,149,000
470,000
827,000
794,000
300
4,637,000
Percent
Difference
-7.5 •
-6.8
-6.4
-6.5
-6.6
-7.6
-6.9
Ul

-------
                                                                                 TABLE 10B


                                                                                 PERSON MILES
MSA
0
1
2
3
4
5
Total
Transit
Base
197,000
104,000
83,000
69,000
6,000
0
489,000
Plan
260,000
168,000
124,000
115,000
10,000
0
678,000
Percent
Difference
31.8
61.9
50.1
67.4
73.0
-
47.8
Automobile Driver
Base
5,723,000
6,213,000
2,452,000
4,788,000
5,607,000
4,000
24,786,000
Plan
4,962,000
5,495,000
2,116,000
4,231,000
4,932,000
4,000
21,716,000
Percent
Difference
-13.3
-11.6
-13.7
-11.6
-12.0
- 2.7
-12.4
Automobile Passenger
Base
2,120,000
2,268,000
855,000
1,698,000
1,921,000
2,000
8,866.000
Plan
2,662,000
2,813,000
1,123,000
2,176,000
2,613,000
2,000
11,380,000
Percent
Difference
25.5
24.0
31.2
28.1
36.0
.2
28.4
Total
Base
8,040,000
8,585,000
3,390,000
6,555,000
7,534,000
6,000
34.111,000
Plan
7,884,000
8,476,000
3,364,000
6,522,000
7,556,000
6,000
33,773,000
Percent
Difference
-19.4
-12.8
- .9
- .5
.3
- 1.8
- 1.0
\J\
Ui

-------
       TABLE IOC

      TRAVEL COST
(100's of 1973 dollars)
Transit Automobile Total
MSA
0
1
2
3
4
5
Total
Base
147
41
46
20
10
0
265
Percent
Plan
210
83
74
45
15
0
429
Difference
42.9
102.4
60.9
125.0
50.0
-
61.9
Base
5,035
5,248
1,983
3,886
4,393
3
20,550
Percent
Plan
13,044
12,174
4,629
8,889
9,129
4
47,850
Difference
159.1
132.0
133.4
128.7
107.8
33.3
132.9
Base
5,182
5,289
2,029
3,906
4,403
3
20,815
Plan
13,254
12,257
4,703
8,934
9,144
4
48,279
Percent
Difference
155.8
131.8
131.8
128.7
107.7
33.3
131.9

-------
 TABLE 10D

TRAVEL TIME
 (Hours)
Transit Automobile Total
MSA
0
1
2
3
4
5
Total
Base
34,157
13,483
10,696
7,893
1,598
0
67,795
Percent
Plan
50,367
24,868
16,998
15,218
2,742
0
110,194
Difference
47.5
84.4
58.9
92.8
71.6
-
62.5
Base
304,459
292,530
113,651
226,359
232,908
152
L, 170, 060
Percent
Plan
299,211
288,943
112,483
225,011
235,416
149
1,165,434
Difference
-1.7
-1.2
1.0
.6
1.1
-2.0
-.4
Base
338,616
306,013
124,347
234,252
234,506
152
1,237,855
Plan
349,578
313,811
129,481
240,229
238,158
149
1,275,628
Percent
Difference
3.2
2.6
4.1
2.6
1.6
-2.0
3.1

-------
                                                       TABLE 10E
                                                  AVERAGE TRAVEL TIME
                                                  PER TRIP  (MINUTES)
MSA
0
1
2
3
, .4
5
Total
Transit
Base
29
39
28
45
19
0
31
Plan
131
37
29
41
21
0
32
Percent
Difference
6.9
-5.1
3.6
-8.9
10.5
-
3.2
Automobile
Base
13
14
14
16
17
32
14
Plan
14
16
16
17
18
34
16
Percent
Difference
7.7
14.3
14.3
6.3
5.9
6.3
14.3
Total
Base
13
15
15
16
17
32
15
Plan
15
16
17
17
18
34
17
Percent
Difference
15.4
6.7
13.3
6.3
5.9
6.3
13.3
oo

-------
      The distribution of. average travel times  per  trip  for automobile
 and transit trips under the base and plan  conditions  is presented in
 Exhibit 3.  The distributions  of travel time for the  base and plan
 conditions for each of the modes are relatively similar.  Generally,
 the proportions of trips under the  plan conditions  is smaller for
 lower ranges of travel time (up to  about 15 to 20 minutes) and greater
 for travel times of 20 to 25 minutes or more.  With automobile trips,
 this reflects an increase in the travel times  for the average trip
 resulting from an increase in  the travel distance of  the average trip
 (the reasons for which were noted above).  This increase in travel
 times is more difficult to explain  for  transit trips  inasmuch as the
 average trip length for transit trips in the plan condition (about
 3.3 miles) is smaller than the average  trip length  for transit trips
 under the base condition (3.5  miles).   These results would suggest
 that those passengers who were provided with the best transit service
 from a travel time perspective were  already using transit in the base
 condition, and that the travelers who were diverted to transit had a
 relatively longer travel time  (in spite of their relatively shorter
 transit travel distance).   The diversion of the travelers to transit
 occurred,  of course,  as a result  of  the significant increase in the
 cost of automobile travel.

      The corresponding travel  cost distribution for automobile vehicle
 trips under  the base  and plan  conditions is presented in Exhibit 4.
 Inasmuch as  the same  transit fare was used under the base and the plan
 conditions,  and this  fare provides a  constant 25c fare for transit
 travel throughout  the San Diego region,  it was not necessary to present
 the travel cost distribution for transit.  The significant increase in
 the cost of  an automobile  trip  that  occurs under the transportation
 control  plan is evident.  Under the base condition, relatively few
 automobile travelers  in the San Diego region paid parking charges for
 either their work  on  their  non-work  trips.   Hence, the travel cost
 distribution  for  the  base period essentially reflects the distance
 related  component  of  the trip,  and the  travel cost distributions for
 the base period decays  approximately as the travel distance distribution
would decay.   Under the plan condition, there are no automobile trips
with an  out-of-pocket  cost of 50
-------
                            EXHIBIT 3
    TRAVEL TIME DISTRIBUTION FOR TOTAL AUTO AND TRANSIT
         PERSON TRIPS FOR BASE AND PLAN CONDITIONS
0-5   5-10   10-15  15-20  20-25 25-30 30-35 35-40 40-45 45-50  50-55  55-60  60+

                       TRAVEL TIME, (MINUTES)
                             60

-------
                                    EXHIBIT  4
                  TRAVEL COST DISTRIBUTION FOR TOTAL AUTO
                   VEHICLE TRIPS BASE AND PLAN CONDITIONS
100.00
         50
1.00
1.50   2.00   2.50  3.00   3.50   4.00   450

          TRAVEL COST (1966 DOLLARS)
550   6.00   6.50+
                                       61

-------
Thus, the most effective approaches for reducing VMT were increases  in
carpooling or foregoing the trip entirely, and these factors had a
relatively equal impact upon the VMT reduction.  While transit travel
increased by 60 percent between the base and the plan conditions, the
diversion for transit accounted for only a relatively small proportion
of the VMT reduction.

     In the short-run, there are other modifications of travel behavior
which a traveler might make in response to a transportation control
plan.  In particular, travelers might choose alternative destinations
for both their work and their non-work trips which were closer to their
residences, thereby reducing the average travel distance per trip.   The
EPA promulgated transportation control plan contains little if any
incentive to achieve this objective, however, inasmuch as the parking
surcharge is independent of the distance of the trip.
                                  62

-------
DEVELOPMENT OF PROGRAM COSTS

     As outlined in Section I of this report, direct program costs were
obtained for program strategies and measures and distributed among the
five groups:

      .  local government  (including San Diego County AQCR, and
        city of San Diego organizations);

      .  state government  (including California state financing
       policies and organizations);

      .  federal government (including federal granting programs,
        financing policies, and federal regional activities);

     .  industry (relating primarily to local San Diego and
       California industry, all inclusive of business and
       commerce); and

     . citizen (includes citizens and consumers in this group,
       and is generally referred to in the case of all employ-
       ment impact discussions).

     This portion of the report discusses the nature of and basis for
cost data obtained for each of the measures, and the general methodolo-
gies utilized to assess, categorize, and apply these costs to each of
the groups outlined above.

Technical Basis for Costs

     Prior technical studies had resulted in a basis for the development
of substantial cost data by EPA and state and local organizations.  The
Region IX studies had concluded that in the case of the San Diego AQCR:

     . The National Ambient Air Quality Standard for photochemical
       oxidants had been exceeded.

     . The nitrogen dioxide ambient air quality standard had not
       been exceeded.  Furthermore, it was anticipated that this
       standard would not be exceeded in the future.

     . The carbon monoxide standard had been exceeded.  However,
       control measures could be taken to reduce photochemical
       oxidants through reactive hydrocarbon (RHC) reductions to
       achieve a carbon monoxide level below the standard.

The State of California's Implementation Plan, Revision 3, submitted
July 28, 1973, for the San Diego air basin concluded that:
                                  63

-------
     . The photochemical oxidant standard could not be met by 1975
       and would require additional control strategies to meet the
       standard by 1977.

     . The nitrogen dioxide standard had not been exceeded in 1970
       and was not projected to be exceeded through 1980.

     . The carbon monoxide standard would be exceeded in 1975, but
       could be met by 1977.

     EPA's conclusions were that implementation of the state plan would
result in much of the required reduction of oxidants, but  would not  be
sufficient to meet the standards.  The Administrator of EPA granted  the
allowable extension of the deadline under Section 110(e) of the Clean
Air Act Amendments of 1970 from 1975 to 1977.  The EPA plan requires
compliance for most emission sources other than motor vehicles by
June 1975.

     An initial observation made on the distribution of socioeconomic
impacts throughout the AQCR was that the majority of the population
that would bear the costs would benefit directly from the improvements
in air quality.  This fact is contrasted to other regions  where air
pollutants are carried across regional borders.  San Diego is affected,
however, by the inflow of uncontrolled vehicles from Mexico.

     For this study, costs were identified and separated into implemen-
tation costs and recurring costs estimated for 1977.  Attempts were  made
to obtain longer range costs to achieve the objectives of assessing  the
duration, the cost-effectiveness, and the degree of impact of each of
the various strategies.  It was not possible to develop specific post-
1977 cost projections from available sources.  For consistency, 1973
dollars have been used throughout the study.

     Implementation costs were not annualized because the majority of
the costs would be one-time costs.  A series of annualized approaches
utilizing various assumptions have been used in past studies.  However,
policies for determining direct or annualized bases for taxing the
population and methods of payment await action by the State of California
legislature and may take entirely different formats than any of the
study approaches that have been suggested.

     The totals for implementation costs to 1977 are shown by impacted
organizational segments in Table 11. Similarly recurring costs during
1977 are totalled in Table 12. Each of the component strategy-cost
areas are detailed in the following discussions.
                                 64

-------
                                                    TABLE  11

                                       TOTAL IMPLEMENTATION COSTS BY 1977
                                                     ($000)
Cn
Source Impact
Stationary
Mobile
VTM
Other
Total Costs
Local
Gov't.
79
-
4,925
-
5,004
State
Gov't.
78
10,000
337
2,000
12,415
Federal
Gov ' t .
77
-
338
8,000
8,415
Industry
10,610
-
-
-
10,610
Citizen
-
44,250
-
-
44,250
Total
10,844
54,250
5,600
10,000
80,694

-------
           TABLE  12
TOTAL RECURRING COSTS IN 1977
           ($000)
Source Impact
Stationary
Mobile
VMT
Other
Total Costs
Local
Gov ' t .
40
678
5,440
4,886
11,044
State
Gov ' t .
40
1,695
69
18,379
20,183
Federal
Gov't.
40
678
69
-
787
Industry
424
-
-
-
424
Citizen
-
33,892
351,019
-
384,911
Total
544
36,943
356,597
23,265
417,349

-------
^Implementation Costs

     Stationary Sources

     The San Diego Air Pollution Control District (APCD) provided data
and cost estimates associated with reactive hydrocarbon reductions.   A
study* by the Rand Corp. was utilized to evaluate data resulting from
in-depth investigations.  The Rand projections to 1975 are generally con-
sidered comparable to 1977 since the majority of fixed installations
are required to be corrected by 1975 in order to comply with the EPA
promulgated plan and the APCD Rules and Regulations.

     In its July 16, 1973, proposed plan, EPA included gasoline vapor
control.  However the gasoline strategy was deleted from the final
promulgated plan in view of the advanced status of the program being
implemented by the San Diego APCD.  This study incorporates this area
in its scope of work.  Estimates of RHC reductions utilized by EPA were
drawn from work performed by the Rand Corp., discussions with the APCD,
and modifications that reflect the EPA reactivity factors for petroleum
plus growth projections.  It should also be noted that the Rand 1975
projections had not incorporated EPA proposals in either RHC reduction
projections or cost estimates.  Cost figures were provided by the APCD
in the areas of local, state, and Federal Government administration and
for industrial equipment and its installation.  The APCD industry imple-
mentation costs per ton of RHC reductions per day is $966 and compares
closely with Rand figures of $950.

     Other stationary sources covered in the promulgated plan included:

     . degreasing operations;

     . metal surface coating thinners and reducers;

     . organic solvent usage; and

     . dry cleaning solvent vapor losses.

The promulgated plan reduced the requirements previously proposed.
Estimated RHC reductions were provided by the APCD.   The Rand study
analyzed the processes and costs in these four areas under a series of
projected requirements.   Their nominal strategy conformed to the proj-
ected requirements of the APCD for 1975.  Rand's series of reference
strategies (i.e., those technically feasible by 1975) were reviewed for
cost significance.
*DeHaven, W.C., and B. M. Woodfill.  Cost and Effectiveness of
 Strategies for Reducing Emissions from Fixed Sources:   The San Diego
 Air Basin, 1975.  Rand Corporation WN-8141-SD.
                                 67

-------
      The  study  team's  conclusions—that implementation costs in these
 four  areas  appeared  to be  insignificant when compared to the magnitude
 of  costs  associated  with implementing other strategies—follow:

        Degreasing,  the major area of RHC reduction, has been projected
        to  require little  change in equipment by substituting nonreac-
        tive  solvents.

      .  Metal coatings, the second major reduction, also involves
        shifting  to  nonreactive solvents and water-based, powdered,
        or  high solids coatings.  No implementation costs were iden-
        tified.

      .  Organic solvents implementation is to be accomplished by sub-
        stitution.   Some vapor recovery equipment may be required.
        Dry cleaning establishments are difficult to control, and
        Rand  conluded  that solvent substitution did not appear to
        be  technically or  economically feasible.  As an alternative,
        Rand  recommended that activated carbon adsorbers be installed
        at  an estimated equipment cost of $425,000 for 166 establish-
        ments.  Solvent recovery values were estimated to permit
        equipment amortization within two years.  EPA's promulgated
        plan  addressed apparent technical difficulties, extended com-
        pliance time by one year (i.e., to 1975), allowed four percent
        RHC content  in solvents, and dropped the required emission
        reduction from 95  percent to 90 percent.  Costs were not
        estimated for  implementation of this area because of the
        difficulties cited and the lack of cost data to comply with
        the promulgated plan.

     A summary  of RHC reductions projected by our sources is shown in
Table 13.   The  associated  direct implementation costs provided by the
APCD are  listed in Table 14.

     Mobile Sources

     Catalytic  converter retrofit implementation costs plus costs for
devices required under state programs were developed and supplied by
the Office  of Environmental Management, County of San Diego, utilizing
the Motor Vehicle Emission and Cost (MOVEC) model developed by the Rand
Corporation.  In addition, projected reductions in RHC were furnished.

     Inspection and maintenance implementation costs were developed
by PMM&Co.  based upon  the projected vehicle population and the need
for loaded  dynamometer inspection stations together with estimates
of associated installation costs.
                                68

-------
                         TABLE 13

 STATIONARY SOURCE REACTIVE HYDROCARBON REDUCTION BY 1977

                         (TONS/DAY)
Stationary Source
Gasoline Vapor
Degreasing Solvents
Metal Coating
Solvents
Organic Solvents
Dry Cleaning Solvents -
Total

>


EPA
31.9

15.8


47.7
APCD
30.1*
6.9
4.2
1.3
0.6.
43.1

>13.0@


Rand
13.9*
14.6
3.7

0.7.
32.9

>19.0@


*7-day week
@5-day week
                            69

-------
                                                    TABLE 14
•vj
o
                        IMPLEMENTATION COSTS FOR STATIONARY SOURCE RHC REDUCTION  BY  1977

                                                     ($000)
Stationary
Sources
Gasoline Vapor
Degreasing Solvents
Metal Coating
Solvents
Organic Solvents
Dry Cleaning Solvents
Total Costs
Local
Gov ' t .
51
2
17
2
7
79
State
Gov ' t .
51
2
16
2
7
78
Federal
Gov't.
51
2
16
2
6
77
Industry Citizen
10,610
0
0
0
0
10,610
Total
10,763
6
49
6
20
10,844

-------
     Catalytic converter retrofits apply to the 1966-1974 model years,
involving 556,300 vehicles of a projected 1977 total of 902,790.  Two
sets of costs were developed, based upon alternate retrofit eligibi-
lities.  Universal Oil Products (UOP) recently advised the San Diego
Office of Environmental Management that their analysis indicated that
significantly more vehicles utilizing the same device could run on 91
RON gasoline.  The basic costs were more conservative, based upon EPA
estimates of eligibility.

     Both sets of costs are illustrated here, but the study team has
elected to use those cost figures based upon the EPA promulgated plan.
Table 15 shows a distribution of vehicles by model year, the percen-
tage of eligible users of devices, and the projected RHC reductions.
Table 16 covers implementation costs for the same alternatives.  Costs
for equipment and installation under the state program apply to
657,090 vehicles representing model years 1955-1974.

     Inspection and maintenance programs to be conducted under the
EPA promulgated plan involving loaded testing will require inspection
stations equipped to perform test programs of significantly more com-
plexity than those performed under the random sampling program cur-
rently in effect.

     Since no cost data have been developed, other than an estimated
range for dynamometers, a set of calculations were made by PMM&Co.
to establish inspection station costs.  On the basis of a state-
conducted annual inspection program including in addition to pollution
control equipment, allowance for the potential incorporation of
vehicle safety inspection, the following rationale was established:

     .  for 900,000 vehicles = 3 600 vehicles per day;
              250 days                              y
     .  with each vehicle requiring 30 minutes, including
        loaded dynamometer test, safety tests, and certi-
        fication or rejection:

     .  during an 8-hour day, 16 vehicles per lane (each
        station to be built with 6 lanes, handling 96 vehicles -
        rounded to 100);

     .  yielding 3.600 vehicles/day  = 36 stations. And
                       100

     .  for each inspection station, 6 lanes wide by 60 feet long
        (to accommodate portions of inspection plus other required
        facilities) = 3,600 square feet;
                                71

-------
                                 TABLE 15





PROJECTED MOBILE SOURCE CONTROLS APPLICABILITY AND RHC REDUCTIONS BY 1977
Numbers of Vehicles Affected by Strategies
Model
Year
1975-77
1972-74
t
1971
1966-70
1961-65
1958-60
Total
Number
245,700
239,400
73,800
243,000
74,700
26,190
902,790
Catalyst Eligibility
UOP

95%1
757.J
60%
	
EPA

75% of
313,200
20%


Crankcase
Blowby


100%

NOX Control
and/or
VSAD

1 100% of
[556,200
J


Pre-1966 Exhaust
Retrofit;
NOX Control
and /or
VSAD


}100% of
100,890

Inspection
Maintenance



L 100% Of
' 902, 790
Reactive Hydrocarbon Reductions - Tons/Day
Rand plus UOP Eligibility 18.6
Rand plus EPA Eligibility
EPA Promulgated Plan
12.0
1
1 19, <; 1
1 I?. ^ I
19.0 1

RHC
Reduction
Totals
31.1
24.5
12.9

-------
                              TABLE 16
        A.
                       IMPLEMENTATION COSTS TO
                      RETROFIT VEHICLES BY 1977

                                ($000)
Source
Equipment
Installation
Total
EPA*
24,850
7,360
32,210
ARB@
8,600
3,440
12,040
Total
33,450
10,800
44,250
        B.
Source
Equipment
Installation
Total
UOP#
37,150
11,380
48,530
ARB@
8,600
3,440
12,040
Total
45,750
14,820
60,570
^Catalytic retrofit eligibility--75% of 1971-74, 207o of 1966-70.
©California Air Resources Board equipment.

      . crankcase blowby--100% of 1955-60;

      . pre-1966 exhaust retrofit—NOX control and/or VSAD, 100% of
       1955-65; and

      . NOX control and/or VSAD, 100% of 1966-70.

^Catalytic retrofit eligibility—95% of 1972-74, 75% of 1971,
 60%  of 1966-70.
                                 73

-------
      .  with building at $20 per square foot  = $72,000

         six dynamometers at $20,000          = 120,000

         other equipment                      = 50,000

         land at 15% of above                 = 36.000
            •
              TOTAL                            $278,000

      .  then 36 stations at $278,000       $10,008,000

Adequate geographic dispersion  to accommodate the population of the
Air Quality Control Region  both to  avoid  concentration and to allow
for growth,  will require detailed study.

      In view of the limiting regulations  on motorcycle operations,
which will  be modified if a national regulation on RHC emissions is
promulgated,  no implementation  costs were developed.  Hardware costs
incorporated in 1976 and later  year models are envisioned along with
associated  administrative and inspection/maintenance costs.  Table 17
shows the mobile source  implementation  costs  allocated to the impacted
groups.

      VMT Reduction

      Exclusive Bus/Carpool  Lanes.  The  Comprehensive Planning Organi-
zations  (CPO)  of the County of  San Diego  is initiating a pilot study
covering 22  ramp and meter  locations including  bypasses.  This cost
has  been shown at $450,000,  split between state and federal funds.

      Bus/Carpool Matching.  A computer  matching and promotion system
was  estimated  by the state/local task force to  cost $175,000 for imple-
mentation.   The promulgated plan modified the  total area approach to
begin with an  initial  pilot evaluation  utilizing selected U. S.  Navy
facilities.

      Parking  Supply.   Implementation of the program for the review
of new commercial  parking facilities involves an initial review and
approval by Region IX with  potential transfer to state and local
authorities.  PMM&Co. has included an estimated figure of $50,000 to
cover  the development  of operational procedures.  The implementation
date  of  this program has been deferred  to January 1,  1975.  (Federal
Register, January  15,  1974.)

     Mass Transit  Incentives.  Implementation cost assignment for
this  employer  incentive program did not appear applicable prior  to
the revision contained in the Federal Register  (January 15,  1974)
which advised  that more general regulations will be issued.
                                  74

-------
                                                     TABLE 17
Ul
                                  IMPLEMENTATION COSTS  FOR MOBILE  SOURCES BY 1977




                                                     ($000)
Mobile Source
Catalyst Retrofit Equipment
ARB Equipment
Inspection/Maintenance Stations
Total Costs
Local
Gov't.
~
-
-
-
State
Gov ' t .
-
-
10,000
10,000
Federal
Govlt.
-
-
-
-
Indus try
-
-
-
-
Citizen
32,210
12,040
-
44,250
Total
32,210
12,040
10,000
54,250

-------
     Parking Surcharge.  Those parking surcharge implementation costs
that could be identified were supplied by the City of San Diego. Al-
ternatives were evaluated for the estimated 76,000 free non-residen-
tial parking spaces, including parking meters.  The capital outlay,
including installation, for parking meters was estimated at $4.8 mil-
lion.  Extensive surveys would be required to identify and inventory
all on-street non-residential and all off-street parking areas.

     Ajr Quality Monitoring.  VMT air quality monitoring was assessed
by the APCD to require six permanent stations plus a number of mobile
installations.   Continuous  monitoring  is  to  be  incorporated  in  future
plans.  No implementation cost data were identified.

     Bicycle Lanes.   The cost of implementing bicycle lanes was esti-
mated by the San Diego Task Force at a preliminary estimate of $5 mil-
lion which could reduce VMT approximately one percent.  The City of
San Diego is evaluating a plan covering 30 bike path proposals at
$125,000.  This later figure has been incorporated in our implementa-
tion costs.

     Four-Day Week.  The four-day week concept has been initiated in
San Diego County for county employees.  The program permits adjustment
of working hours so that the required 80 hours are worked during each
two weeks and so that rescheduling does not require additional person-
nel.  No implementation costs appeared applicable.

     Table 18 is a listing of VMT reduction implementation costs
accrued by 1977.

     Other Measures.  Aircraft operational impacts have been studied
extensively by Rand and the California Air Resources Board.  EPA's  pro-
mulgated plan notes that the Agency will continue to assess the feasi-
bility of proposed controls working with the Federal Aviation Adminis-
tration.  It appears premature to assign implementation costs at this
stage of the program.

     The expansion of mass transit involves increasing the number of
buses in the fleet in addition to allowing for the replacement of re-
tired vehicles.  The San Diego Transit Corporation plans to expand  its
present fleet of 250 buses to 350 by 1977.  It has been estimated by
the Comprehensive Planning Organization (CPO) that to respond to the
EPA promulgated plan, an additional 200 buses will be required in 1977.
San Diego Transit's estimate of $50,000 per bus translates into an
implementation cost of $10 million.  Under current law, the Urban Mass
Transit Agency (UMTA) is permitted to fund 80 percent of the capital
cost.  The remaining 20% has been allocated to the state for funding
under its S.B. 325 program which is accomplished, through state sales
taxes.  In 1972, the sales tax structure was increased 0.25 percent,
and the base was extended to include gasoline taxes.  Additional funds
generated by this measure were to be allocated to transportation devel-
opment.  In counties with populations greater than 500,000, the funds
                                 76

-------
                 TABLE 18

VMT REDUCTION IMPLEMENTATION COSTS BY 1977
                  ($000)
VMT Source
Exclusive Bus/
Carpool Lanes
Bus/Carpool
Matching
Parking Supply
Mass Transit
Incentives
Parking Surcharge
VMT Air Quality
Monitoring
Bicycle Lanes
4-Day Week
Total
Local
Gov't.
-
-
-
-
4,800
-
125
-
4,925
State
Gov ' t .
225
87
25
•*
-
-
-
-
337
Federal
Gov't.
225
88
25
-
-
-
-
-
338
Industry
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
Citizen
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
Total
450
175
50
-
4,800
-
125
-
5,600

-------
were  to be  spent for the development, maintenance, and operation of
public transportation systems.  Thus, $8 million implementation cost
has been allocated to the Federal Government and $2 million to the
state.  Cost allocations are shown in Table 19.

Recurring Costs

      Recurring cost data, expressed in 1973 dollars, represent those
identified  costs projected to occur during 1977 and are based upon
completion  of the implementation portion of the strategies prior to
1977.

      Stationary source costs were supplied by APCD.  A total of $80,000
was assigned to administration and field operations involved in enforce-
ment  of APCD Rules and Regulations in effect at that time which would
incorporate state requirements combined with the EPA promulgated plan.

      An estimated $424,000 was assigned to the petroleum industry for
permits, equipment maintenance, and operations.  It was estimated that
the use of  vapor control equipment would recover gasoline vapor equiv-
alent to $1.1 million annually.  This savings to the industry at $0.40
per gallon would be equivalent to an additional 2,750,000 gallons of
gasoline.

      The significance of projected costs and savings resulting from
vapor recovery and materials substitution in the other four stationary
areas were  addressed in the Rand study. In the Rand nominal strategy.
for 1975, available costs and savings data were minor and offsetting,
resulting a net figure approximating zero.  Table 20 indicates recurring
costs for stationary sources.

      Mobile source recurring costs include conducting an annual inspec-
tion  and maintenance program to assure the operational efficiency of
vehicles equipped with the required RHC reduction devices.  Estimated
increases in operating costs resulting from additional gasoline con-
sumption were also provided.  The costs, provided by the Office of
Environmental Management of the County of San Diego, were developed
utilizing the MOVEC model, incorporating the same series of inputs used
in generating the implementation costs for hardware and installation.
Table 21 compares alternate costs utilizing EPA and UOP eligibilities
for catalytic converters.  Costs for California Air Resources Board
equipment for maintenance/operating cost increases are included.  No
local estimates were available for loaded dynamometer testing.  A figure
of $4.50 per vehicle was obtained from the national average figure
contained in an EPA white paper.*
*Holtnes, J., J. Horowitz, R, Reid, and P. Stolpman.  The Clean Air Act
 and Transportation Controls, an EPA White Paper.  Office of Air and
 Water Programs, Environmental Protection Agency.  Washington, D.C. :
 August 1973.

                                  78

-------
                  TABLE  19
OTHER REDUCTION IMPLEMENTATION COSTS BY 1977




                   ($000)
Other Sources
Aircraft Ground Operations
Bus Requirements
Total Costs
Local
Gov ' t .
-
-
-
State
Gov ' t .
-
2,000
2,000
Federal
Gov ' t .
-
8,000
8,000
Industry
-
-
-
Citizens
-
-
-
Total
-
10,000
10,000

-------
                                              TABLE  20


                       RECURRING COSTS FOR STATIONARY SOURCES DURING 1977

                                              ($000)
CO
o
Stationary
Source
Gasoline Vapor
Degreasing
Solvents
Metal
Coating
Organic Solvents
Dry Cleaning
Solvents
Total Costs
Local
Gov ' t .
26
1

8
1
4
40
State
Gov't.
26
1

8
1
4
40
Federal
Gov't.
26
1

8
1
4
40
Industry
424
-

-
-
-
424
Citizen
-
-

-
-
-
-
Total
502
3

24
3
12
544

-------
                     TABLE 21
   RECURRING COSTS FOR INSPECTION/MAINTENANCE
PROGRAM AND INCREASED OPERATING COSTS DURING 1977
                     ($000)
         A.  EPA Eligibility Assumptions
Mobile Source
Inspection
Loaded Mode
Maintenance!?
Operating
Total*
EPA .

4,930
3,930
8,860
ARE

18,750
22,220
20,970
Total
4,062*
23,680
6,150
33,892
         B.  UOP Eligibility Assumptions
Mobile Source
Inspection
Loaded Mode
Maintenance^
Operating
Total*
EPA

7,260
5,700
12,960
ARE

18,750
2,220
20,970
Total
4,062*
26,010
7,920
37,992
* Based upon 902,790 vehicles at $4.50 per vehicle.

@ OEM, San Diego.

# OEM  San Diego at fuel cost of $0.40 per gallon.
                       81

-------
     Administrative costs for government involvement in the program were
estimated by PMM&Co.  Two percent of the inspection and maintenance
poritions of the combined total of $33,892,000 was allocated to local
and federal governments and five percent was alloted to the state govern-
ment.  All of the above costs are allocated in Table 22.

     VMT reduction recurring costs are based upon the EPA promulgated
plan.  The parking surcharge cost to local government was supplied  by
the City of San Diego and represents an estimate covering the administra-
tion, maintenance, and collection of fees for the additional parking
meters.

     The balance of the costs associated with this series of strategies
were developed by PMM&Co.  Figures covering exclusive bus/car-pool  lanes were
estimated at $2,300 per ramp to cover maintenance and operations based on
data developed from Los Angeles.  Bus/car-pool matching costs were  based
upon manpower requirements to operate and update the system at $58,000
per year.  The parking supply strategy was estimated to incur $30,000
per year in administrative costs.

     Mass transit incentive and parking surcharge costs to industry and
citizens were .developed utilizing the PMM&Co. n-dimensional logit model.
This area is discussed in detail in Section II.  VMT air quality moni-
toring, bicycle lane maintenance, and four-day work week program impacts
were not assigned recurring costs because of non-availability of quanti-
tative data.  Table 23 portrays the allocation of costs among the groups.

     Aircraft ground operations were studied by Rand and the California
Air Resources Board.  No recurring costs were incorporated for this
potential measure.

     The recurring costs for operating buses—reflecting an increase  in
operating losses over revenues for a 1977 bus fleet of 550 vehicles,
were developed by PMM&Co. based upon data furnished by the San Diego
Transit Corporation.

     Operating costs are estimated to run $70,000 per bus in 1977.  This
figure adjusted to 1973 dollars becomes $58,874 or a total for 550  buses
of $32,353,000.  Operating revenues, based upon 1973 history of 19.3£
per rider realized from a fare rate of 25c, with deductions for students,
elderly, and monthly rates, projected at 19C per rider to 1977, but
adjusted in 1973 dollars to 16.2c, combined with a projection of 204,000
daily transit trips in 1977,and utilizing a 275 day year as the transit
equivalent of workdays per year, results in a revenue figure of $9,088,000.
The resulting operating deficit becomes $23,265,000.  This deficit  was
allocated 21 percent to local government and 79 percent to state support
under S.B. 325 funding as shown in Table 24.
                                 82

-------
                                                    TABLE  22
                                 RECURRING COSTS FOR MOBILE  SOURCES DURING 1977
                                                      ($000)
Mobile Source
Inspection
Maintenance
Operating
Administrative
Total
Local
Gov ' t .
-
-
-
678
678
State
Gov ' t .
-
-
-
1,695
1,695
Federal
Gov't.
-
-
-
678
678
Industry
-
-
-
*
Citizen
4,062
23,680
6,150
-
33,982
Total
4,062
23,680
6,150
3,051
36,943
O3
U)

-------
                                                     TABLE 23


                                 VMT REDUCTION STRATEGY RECURRING COSTS IN 1977
                                                      ($000)
VMT Strategies
Exclusive Bus/
Carpool Lanes
Bus/Carpool
Matching
Parking Supply
Mass Transit
Incentives
Parking Surcharge
VMT Air Quality
Monitoring
.Bicycle Lanes
4-Day Week
Total
Local
Gov ' t .
-
-
-
-
5,440
-
-
-
5,440
State
Gov't.
25
29
15
-
-
-
-
-
69
Federal
Gov't.
25
29
15
-
-
-
-
-
69
Industry
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
Citizen
-
-
-
56,626
294,393
-
-
-
351,019
Total
50
58
30
56,626
299,833
-
-
-
356,597
09
•P-

-------
                                              TABLE  24


                                  OTHER RECURRING  COSTS  DURING 1977
Mobile Sources
Aircraft Ground
Operations
Bus Requirements
Total
Local
Gov ' t .
-
4,882
4,882
State
Gov ' t .
-
18,365
18,365
Federal
Gov't.
-
•
Industry
-
-
Citizen
-
-
Total
\
23.247
23,247
00
Ul

-------
ALLOCATION RATIONALE

Allocation of Costs to Citizens

     The previous chapters described the methodologies  for  obtaining
the estimated costs for each of the measures,  and then  identifying  the
direct cost impact on the five major groups.

     This portion of the report further develops the rationale  and
describes the methodologies for further allocation of the program costs
from four of the groups to the citizens in such a manner that program
costs can be determined by the various income  stratifications.

     In addition to describing the techniques  applied for distribution
of each group, the program costs for one-time  implementation, and the
estimated annual operating costs are shown as  a percent of  income of
the citizens of San Diego.  Four income strata were utilized for
determining the effect on households in the San Diego AQCR.  These  are:

     . under $5,000;

     . 5,000 to 10,000;

     . 10,000 to 15,000; and

     . over $15,000.

Allocation Methodologies

     For allocation purposes, it has been assumed that  certain  costs
will be incurred by local government, state government, and Federal
Government as well as industry in controlling  stationary and mobile
pollution sources.  Additionally, costs will be incurred  in enforcing
regulations to be employed in reducing vehicle miles traveled and
diminishing other air pollution sources.

     Ultimately, the taxpayer in the case of government and the user  in
the case of industry are called upon to pay the costs of  improved living
conditions or advances in technology.  In the  past, government  has  gone
to great lengths to soften the economic impact of taxation.  The  real
property tax is the major source of local government funding while  state
and Federal Government rely primarily on income taxes.   Industry, for its
part, attempts to pass government imposed taxes directly onto the
consumer in the form of direct and indirect price increases.

     There are numerous potential ways of allocating the burden of
government taxation by imposing special taxes  on households, automobile
owners, gasoline, energy/utilities, employee payrolls,  parking, admis-
sions, sales, corporate incomes, and employers.  This report of the
                                  86

-------
impact of direct implementation and recurring costs to San Diego area
residents has utilized present policy and is generally based on real
property taxes in the case of local government costs, personal income
taxes of households (married taxpayers filing a joint return) for both
state and Federal government costs, and increased gas prices at the
pump in the case of industry.

     Costs were allocated to households by income group and in some
instances, on the basis of vehicles owned and estimated miles driven
per household.  Utilizing the strategies described under Program Costs,
a methodology for allocating source costs at the local, state, Federal,
industry, and citizen levels was developed.

     Base line data on population and number of households, vehicle
ownership, and average miles driven per vehicle by various income
groups in the San Diego area was drawn from previously referenced Rand
estimates for 1975 and from the County Office of Environmental Manage-
ment data and cost estimating model (MOVEC).  The estimated number of
households by income group in 1975 was:

           Income Group                  Number of Households

           Under $5,000                  142,500        (287,)

           $5,000 - 10,000               154,800        (30%)

           $10,000 - 15,000              119,900        (23%)

           Over $15,000                   97.200        (19%)
           Total                         514,400       (100%)

     On an average annual basis between 1970 and 1975, the San Diego
area is expected to grow at a rate of approximately 9,300 households
containing 2.9 persons.  Between 1975 and 1980, approximately 10,000
additional households per year are projected for the study area.  The
assumption was made that the percentage distribution of households by
income group would be the same throughout the six years.

     Personal consumption expenditure data developed by the U.S. Depart-
ment of Labor/Bureau of Labor Statistics was used as the basis for
establishing estimated taxable incomes per household within each of the
income ranges of $2,600, $7,700, $13,800, and $30,100.

     Implementation costs for federal and state sources were then
allocated to each income group using the estimated taxable income per
household as the basis for determining economic impact.  Local impact
was estimated based on property taxes and industry impact on miles
driven per household unit with one or more vehicles.  Rand data on
estimated user costs was employed in estimating citizen costs.
                                 87

-------
     The basis for allocations by major groups follow:

 Local  Government

     The assumption was made, based on statistical experience in other
 communities, that 45 percent of total 1977 San Diego households would
 own their place of residence according to income group  as follows:

               Income Group               % Owning Home

               Under $5,000                  - 0 -

               $5,000 - 10,000                 5%

               $10,000 - 15,000               35%

               Over $15,000                   60%

     A further assumption was made that the market value of an individual
 home would be approximately 2-1/2 times the estimated taxable income of
 a household within each income group as follows:

                        Average Market     Average Property Tax
     Income Group      Value of Dwelling   	Per Dwelling	

     Under $5,000           -0-                    -0-

     $5,000 - 10,000       $19,250                $436

     $10,000 - 15,000       34,500                $870

     Over 15,000            75,250              $1,900

 San Diego property taxes in 1973 were $10.10 per $100 of assessed value,
which represented 25 percent of market value and amounted to the esti-
mated property taxes shown above.

     On the assumption that the local portion of stationary implementa-
 tion costs are to be allocated on a real property basis, these taxes
per household unit were multiplied by total households  within each of
 the four income groups to produce an estimated 1977 property tax.  Dis-
 tribution of the estimated local portion of air pollution stationary
 costs was completed on a percentage basis so that total group contribu-
 tion would impose the same proportionate burden as real property taxes
by income group.  Household costs by income group are expected to be
0.0, 9.2 cents, 18.3 cents, and 40.1 cents.
                                88

-------
State Government:

     Estimated state personal income taxes as filed by married taxpayers
filing a joint return has been selected as the basis for measuring the
impact of these costs on San Diego households.  Utilizing average esti-
mated taxable incomes per household multiplied by the estimated number
of 1977 household units within each income group would generate approxi-
mately $340.3 million in total state personal income taxes.   Allocating
costs on the same percentage basis as each income group contributes to
state personal income taxes produces the impact per household by income
group.

Federal Government

     In this case, estimated federal personal taxable incomes for
married taxpayers filing a joint return were used as the basis for
determining the impact of these costs on San Diego households.  Average
estimated federal taxable income by household within each income group
was multiplied by the expected 1977 households to generate a tax of
$1,407.1 million.  Following a percentage distribution approach, the
the Federal Government pollution control costs plus individual house-
hold impacts were developed.

Industry

     For purposes of determining the impact of an estimated $10.6 mil-
lion in industry stationary implementation costs, PMM&Co. utilized
Office of Environmental Management MOVEC computed estimates  that 8,320.2
million  miles will be driven in the San Diego area during 1977.  Of
this figure, 837o or 6905.8 million miles will be driven by vehicles
owned by households.

     Under this assumption, the estimated miles to be driven in 1977 by
households with vehicles in each income group were divided by an average
of 13.22 miles per gallon to produce the 522.4 million gallons of gas
consumed by household vehicles in 1977.  These estimated gallons distri-
buted by income group for households with vehicles were then multiplied
by 1.7
-------
               Est. Miles Driven
     Income    Per Household With
     Group        Vehicles 1977

Under $5,000        13,045

$5,000 - 10,000     17,132

$10,000 - 15,000    20,975

Over $15,000        23,869
Average Gallons
of Gas Required
 Per Household
 With Vehicle

      986

     1295

     1586

     1806
Average Estimated
Cost Per Household
   With Vehicle

    $13.91

     18.27

     22.38

     25.48
     The rationale behind these adjustments rests on the fact that
statistical data, taken from the previously referenced Rand studies,
indicates that only 750,000 (83%) of the area's estimated total of
900,000 vehicles were allocated to San Diego area households by income
group.

     Therefore, in the case of estimated industry stationary implementa-
tion costs of $10.6 million, only 83 percent ($8.8 million) was distri-
buted among households by income group.  The remaining $1.8 million
would have to be allocated to the remaining 150,000 non-household vehi-
cles (e.g., commercial) at an average cost of $12.02.  Similarly,
industry stationary recurring costs of $424,000 were distributed on the
same 83 percent basis, and the remaining $72,000 are allocated to the
150,000 non-household vehicles (e.g., commercial) at an average cost of
48 cents.

Citizen/Consumer

     In distributing estimated implementation and recurring costs for
mobile strategies the Rand statistical data reflecting estimated "user"
costs was employed.

     Again, the costs utilized represented 83 percent of the total costs
involved, and therefore, the remaining $7.4 million in mobile implementa-
tion cost must be allocated to the 150,000 non-household vehicles at an
average cost of $49.87 per vehicle.  Similarly, mobile recurring costs of
approximately $5.0 million would have to be allocated to 150,000 non-
household vehicles at an average cost of $33.61 per vehicle.

Implementation Costs

     Table 25 portrays the allocation of estimated implementation costs.
Expected implementation costs by 1977 of $80.7 million were identified.
Of this amount, local government would pay $5.0 million, state govern-
ment $12.4 million, Federal Government $8.4 million, industry $10.6 mil-
lion, and the citizen owning vehicles $44.3 million.
                                 90

-------
                                                        TABLE 25
                                   ESTIMATED  IMPLEMENTATION  COSTS  FOR AIR
                                POLLUTION CONTROL IN SAN DIEGO AREA  BY  1977
INCOME GROUP
Under $5,000
I - Stationary
II - Mobile
III - VMT
IV - Other
$5,000-510,000
I - Stationary
II - Mobile
III - VMT
IV - Other
$10,000-$15,000
I - Stationary
II - Mobile
III - VMT
IV - Other

OVer $15,000
i I - Stationary
II - Mobile
III - VMT
IV - Other
LOCAL
$ 0
0

.09
5.78

.18
11.55
—

.40
25.30
STATE
$ 0
.74
.03
.15
.04
5.16
.17
1.03
.13
17.10
.58
3.42

.54
68.61
2.30
13.72
FEDERAL
$ .02
.09
.59
.07
.32
4.12
.15
.65
13.68

.44
1.89
54.88
INDUSTRY (1)
(Household Only)
$13.91
—

18.27
—

22.38
—
—

25.48
CITIZEN (2)
(Household Only)
$ ~
70.83
—

80.62
__

89.11
—
—

90.37
TOTAL
$ 13.93
71.57
.12
.74
$ 86.36
18.47
85.78
6.27
5.15
$ 115.67
22.84
106.21
12.78
17.10
$ 158.93
26.86
158.98
29.49
68.60
$ 283.93
(1) Non-household industry costs of  $1.8 million would be allocated to 150,000 non-household vehicles at an average cost of $12.02 per vehicle.
(2) Non-household citizen costs of $7.4 million would be allocated to 150,000 non-household vehicles at an average cost of $49.87 per vehicle.

-------
     Table 25 reflects the expected economic impact of implementation  on
the average household in each of four income categories.   In the case  of
households earning less than $5,000, air pollution implementation costs
have been estimated at 86.36 by 1977 with major cost being the $70.83
charge for mobile costs assigned to households.  Figure 2 depicts the
estimated impact of implementation on households.  Implementation costs
then range upward for the average household as income increases as
follows:

          Household     Total Implementation Cost   °L of Net Taxable Income

      Under $5,000              $ 86.30                      3.3

      $5,000 - 10,000            115.61                      1.5

      $10,000 - 15,000           158.93                      1.1

      Over $15,000               283.93                      0.009
     Implementation costs for local, state, and federal government were
estimated at $79,000, $78,000, and $78,000 respectively as shown in
Table 11 and are expected to involve very minor charges to households  in
income groups below $15,000.  For household earning over $15,000, the
allocation of mobile costs for required state inspection stations, and
the federal charge of $8.0 million for new buses under Other Costs
appear substantial.  Industry costs of $10.6 million by 1977 for vapor
control equipment were distributed on the basis of estimated miles
driven, as described earlier in this section, and result in a more equal
allocation of these costs against households with vehicles within each
income group.  Citizen costs of $44.2 million for retrofit hardware and
installation are expected to exert the major implementation cost impact
on households with the most number of vehicles, because the cost differ-
ences by income group in the Citizen column Table 25 reflect the slight
difference in average number of vehicles owned per household.  For pur-
poses of this impact analysis, only 83 percent of the estimated $10.6
and $44.3 million in industry and citizen implementation costs were
distributed among households.  The remaining $1.8 and $7.4 million in
these categories were allocated to 150,000 non-household vehicles at
an average cost of $12.02 and $49.87 per vehicle.

     In summary, the $44.3 million cost of retrofit hardware and instal-
lation is expected to be the single largest outlay of any implementation
cost.  It accounts for 82 percent of the total cost for the average
households earning less than $5,000, but only 32 percent of the much
                                 92

-------
VO
OJ
          DOLLAR
          OUTLAY
$300


 250


 200


 150


 100


1  50


   0
                                            (IN 1973 DOLLARS)
                                                DOLLAR
                                                OUTLAY
                                                     PERCENT DISTRIBUTION
                                     I
I
I
I
                        $5,000
                       $10,000      $15,000      $20,000

                          ANNUAL INCOME PER HOUSEHOLD
                   $25,000
                   $30,000
                                     PERCENT
                                       OF
                                     INCOME
                                       5%
                                       4
                                       3
                                       2
                                       1
                                       0
              FIGURE 2:  ESTIMATED IMPACT OF IMPLEMENTATION COSTS ON SAN DIEGO
                         HOUSEHOLDS AT TAXABLE INCOMES ACCUMULATED THROUGH 1976

-------
larger total implementation cost allocated to household earning over
$15,000 annually.  To the extent that households in income categories
below $10,000 and particularly those under $5,000, could be attracted
to mass transit and thereby reduce the current average of 1.3 and 1.6
vehicles per household, the remaining dollar impact of implementation
costs on these households of $15.53 and 35.05 respectively would be
minimized.

Recurring Costs^

     As previously indicated, recurring costs are those of a non-
capital nature that are projected to recur beginning with 1977.  They
have been estimated at $417.3 million, with local and state government
each incurring over $11 and $20 million respectively,Federal Government
approximately $800,000, industry $424,000, and San Diego citizens the
major share $385 million.  Table 26 indicates the anticipated impact of
1977 recurring costs on an average household in each of four income
categories:

     Households      Total Recurring Costs    % of Net Taxable Income

     Under $5,000         $  598.59                    23.0

     $5,000 - 10,000         802.74                    10.4

     $10,000 - 15,000      1,011.98                     7.4

     Over $15,000          1,276.56                     4.2
     As shown in Figure 3, the most significant economic impact of
recurring costs during 1977 would be on the Citizen group as a result
of the November 12 promulgated surcharge program.

      Including the surcharge program,annual recurring costs of between
$598 (under $5,000), and $1,276, (over $15,000) would result.  For
example, within the first income category, taxable income per household
was estimated at $2,600.  For the average household earning under
$5,000 recurring Citizen/VMT costs of $552 alone would amount to 21 per-
cent of total taxable income.  For households in the over $15,000 income
range in which average taxable income is expected to approach $30,100 by
1977, this same recurring cost would amount to between three percent and
four percent of average total taxable income.  While it is conceivable
that many households earning over $15,000 annually would continue to
consider an automobile essential, it seems likely that the second car
might be eliminated by all but the very high income households.  For
                                   94

-------
                                                                    TABLE  26


                                           ESTIMATED  RECURRING COSTS  FOR AIR  POLLUTION

                                                CONTROL IN SAN DIEGO AREA DURING 1977
vo
(M
INCOME GROUP
Under $5,000
I - Stationary
II - Mobile
III - VMT
IV - Other

$5, 000- $10, 000
I - Stationary
II - Mobile
III - VMT
IV - Other

$10,000-$15,000
I - Stationary
II - Mobile
III - VMT
IV - Other

Over $15,000
I - Stationary
Hi- Mobile
III - VMT
IV - Other

LOCAL

0
0
0
0


.05
.80
6.39
5.74


.09
1.59
12.76
11.46


.21
3.48
27.95
25.11

STATE

0
.13
0
1.36


.02
.87
.04
9.48


.07
2.90
.12 •
31.44


.27
11.63
.47
126.10

FEDERAL

.01
.19
.02
—


.04
.64
.06
—


.08
1.31
.13
—


.22
3.81
.39
—

INDUSTRY (1)
(Household Only)

.52
__
--
—


.69
—
--
—


.85
—
—
—


.98
«
..
__

CITIZEN (2)
(Household Only)

—
44.20
552.16
	


—
52.96
725.20
—


—
61.02
888.16
—


—
65.14
1,010.80
—

TOTAL

.53
44.52
552.18
1.36
598.59

,80
55.27
731.69

802! 98

1.09
66.82
901.17
_42A90_
1,011.98

1.68
84.06
1,039.61
151.21
1,276.56
            (1) Non-household industry costs of $72,000 would be allocated to 150,000 non-household vehicles at an average cost of 48 cents per vehicle.
            (2) Non-household citizen costs of $5.0 million would be allocated to 150,000 non-household vehicles at an average cost $33.61 per vehicle.

-------
vo
DOLLAR
OUTLAY
 $1,400

 1,300

 1,200

  1,100

  1,000

   900

   800

   700

   400

   500

   400
                                          (IN 1973 DOLLARS)
                                                   DOLLAR
                                                   OUTLAY
                                                     PERCENT DISTRIBUTION
                                   I
I
I
                                       PERCENT
                                         OF
                                       INCOME
                                      - 40%
                                         35
                                         30
                                         25
                                         20
                                         15
                                         10
                                         5
                                         0;
                      $5,000       $10,000      $15,000      $20,000     -$25,000

                                   ANNUAL INCOME PER  HOUSEHOLD
                                                                       $30,000
              FIGURE 3:  ESTIMATED  IMPACT OF  RECURRING  COSTS ON SAN DIEGO
                          HOUSEHOLDS AT TAXABLE  INCOMES: 1977

-------
those households earning between $5,000 and $15,000  and required  to pay
recurring costs amounting to more than 10% and 7% of their respective
average taxable incomes of $7,000 and $13,800, continued vehicle  owner-
ship could be expected to significantly change the life-style  of  the
average household within these income groups.

     In summary, the $351.0 million of proposed recurring surcharge cost
to be imposed on San Diego households owning vehicles appears  substantial.
Some reduction in vehicle ownership among the  lower  income households
could be attained by the imposition of proposed implementation costs, but
the imposition of the recurring surcharges on  citizens who found  a vehi-
cle necessary for regular use would result in  a heavy financial burden.

     The estimated recurring cost of measures  excluding the  surcharge
program would be as follows:
               Hous ehoId s

             Under $5,000

             $5,000 - 10,000

             $10,000 - 15,000

             Over $15,000
     Total
Recurring Costs

   $ 45.90

     77.54

    143.81

    265.77
   % of Net
Taxable Income

     1.7

     1.0

     1.0

     0.008
                                 97

-------
REVENUE ANALYSIS

     Previous portions of this report have described the sources and
allocation methodologies of costs directly associated with program
measures.  For each dollar of those costs allocated to the groups identi-
fied, there has also been a dollar of revenue generated for a group.

     Some data for evaluating the flow of revenue has been referenced in
prior air quality studies.-^   The need for revenue analysis had recently been
noted in a Council on Environmental Quality Study2, but as yet, no com-
pleted revenue analysis of San Diego or any other AQCR has been found.
Consequently, in order to complete the development of socio-economic
methodologies, PMM&Co. has devised a rudimentary revenue analysis.

     The revenue analysis was limited to direct revenue flow at group
levels and should be tempered by the following qualifications.

        The potential impact of the flow of revenue to international,
        other non-California or non-San Diego locations was not
        evaluated.

        Potential lags in revenue expenditures and impact on other
        economic multiplier effects were not studied.

        Probably impacts and the application of local government
        generated revenue, new employment (e.g., skill mixes, and
        inflation) were not considered except for developing an
        estimate of increased direct AQCR employment at an average
        wage level.

        Possible consumer psychological behavior changes due to
        unusual or uncommon influences such as gasoline rationing.
1 Economic Impact Assessment of Alternative Transportation Control
Strategies, Final Report of EPA Contract #08-01-0565, Stephen Sobotka &
Co., Environmental Protection Agency, Washington, D.C., May 3, 1973.

2 The Impact on the Distribution of Income of Financing Federally
Required Pollution Control, N.S. Dorfman and A. Snow, Public Interest
Economics Center, Washington, D. C., August 15, 1973.
                                  98

-------
     A  significant point concerning possible reluctance of employees to
use mass  transit could be that, under present interpretations of the
income  tax regulations, funds provided by employers to employees to
encourage transit use could be considered a portion of commuting expense
and therefore would not be normally deductable.

     An analysis of the revenue flows generated by the implementation
portion of the program indicated that governmental agencies would not
benefit directly.  Industry, covering equipment requirements, and the
group designated as citizen/employees, those whose services would be
required  for construction, equipment installation, and administration
of the  program, plus those selling needed land, would be the direct
beneficiaries.  Approximately 75 percent of the funds would flow to
industry, generally located outside of the local area, and 25 percent
would be  directed to new, mostly one-time, employment.  The distribution
is shown  in Table 27.

     Approximately eighty percent of the $19,838,000 of revenue directed
to the  citizen/employee group could be expected to be utilized for jobs,
the remainder being absorbed primarily in overhead.  Assuming an installa-
tion phase of four years and an average income of $10,000, an annual em-
ployment  impact of approximately 397 could be expected during this period.
The majority of these opportunities could be anticipated to develop within
the San Diego AQCR.

Recurring Revenues

     PMM&Co. has considered transit operations a part of local government
for purposes of displaying the flow of revenue at ninety percent of funds
collected from surcharge programs.  It was assumed that the remaining ten
percent of the funds collected would be utilized as direct income to the
citizen/employee group in the form of wage-income for administrative and
maintenance.  Direct revenue accruing also includes new employment require-
ments.  A more complete analysis of revenue flow could show flow from
local government revenue directly into industry and also into employment.
Total revenue accruing to the three groups, shown in Table 28, is projected
at $417,349,000.  Of this amount, $356,459,000 can be attributed to parking
surcharge and mass transit incentives measures.

     Assuming that 80 percent of the citizen/employee and 60 percent of the
industry/employee group revenues would be utilized for employment, the
amount of $74,421,000 would provide 7,442 positions at the average projected
income of $10,000.  The majority of these positions would be related to
vehicle inspection and maintenance, fee collection, transit operations,
and administration.

Analysis of Implementation Cost Per Revenue Group

     The flow of money on a group-by-group basis as-a result of the im-
plementation of the Clean Air Act is projected in Table 29.  This projection
indicates that during the 1972-76 periods, there is a negative flow for all
government agencies and local citizens and a positive flow for industry
                                  99

-------
                               TABLE 27
                        IMPLEMENTATION REVENUES
                                ($000)
Measures
Indus try
Citizen/Employee
Stationary Sources

     Equipment
     Construction
     Administrative

Mobile Sources

     Retrofit
       Equipment
     Installation
     Inspection Stations
       Equipment
       Construction
       Land

VMT Reduction

     Parking Meters
       Equipment
       Installation
     Administration
     Bicycle Lane
       Construction
Other
     Buses
Total
 6,366
33,450


 7,200
 3,840
10,000
60,856
                              4,244
                                234
   10,800
                              1,504
                              1,296
                                960
                                675

                                125
   19,838
                                  100

-------
                               TABLE 28

                          RECURRING REVENUES

                                ($000)
Measures
Stationary Sources

   Maintenance
   Adminis tration

Mobile Sources

   Inspection
   Maintenance
   Operation
   Administration

VMT Reduction

   Mass Transit
   Parking Surcharge
   Adminis tration

Other

   Transit Operations
Total
 Local
 Gov't.
 50,963
264,954
315,917
Industry/
Employee
                  424
               23,680
                6,150
                3,370
33,624
 Citizen/
 Employee
                       120



                     4,062


                     3,051
                     5,663
                    34,879
                       138
                    19,895
67,808
                                 101

-------
            TABLE 29

IMPLEMENTATION REVENUE CASH FLOW
              ($000)
Local
Gov't.
]ost 5,004
levenue
Set Flow -5,004
State
Gov't.
12,415
-
-12,415
Federal
Gov't.
8,415
-
-8,415
Industry
10,610
60,856
+50,246
Citizen
44,250
19,838
-24,412
Total
80,694
80,694
_— .
             102

-------
of $50.2 million.  A major item causing the negative cash flow from
the citizen group combined with the positive flow to industry is the
potential retrofit converter program.  Although it is considered beyond
the scope of this study, comparative economic analyses of the cost-
effectiveness relating projected lives of retrofitted models over an
extended period of time beyond 1977 compared to RHC reductions antici-
pated to be achieved could be useful for policy and regulation inputs.

Analysis of Recurring Cost per Revenue Group

     Annual projected net money flows on a recurring basis following
program implementation is projected in Table 30.  The projection indicates
a potential negative flow in 1977 from the citizens, the state government
and the federal government compared to positive flows to local government
and industry.  The impact of the parking surcharge and mass transit in-
centives are substantial.  Their deletion would eliminate the positive
flow of ..money to the local government, specifically to mass transit.
Elimination of these would also reduce to $6.6 million the projected nega-
tive flow of money from the citizen group as shown in Table 31.  A pro-
gressive financial policy could result by elimination of these measures,
if mass transit were provided with money through other government financing
policies.  The negative impact on costs to the citizens could thus be
reduced while maintaining the direct positive impact on that portion of
local employment opportunities related to mass transit operations.

Fuel Consumption Impacts^

     The impacts of the strategies upon a reduction in gasoline consumption
have been compiled and are summarized in Table 32.  Their relative signi-
ficance in volume and value are indicated.  Vapor control in gasoline
marketing is a positive conservation tool that combined with RHC reduction
remains relatively low in cost.  An increase in gasoline consumption result-
int from retrofitting existing vehicles is anticipated due to the lowering
of efficiencies.  The most significant area of gasoline usage reduction
results from lower VMT and occurs in direct proportion to the amount achieved.
The basis for determining VMT reduction savings was estimated conservatively
using the daily VMT  reduction of 3.07 million miles coupled with the rationale
that this would apply on work days only, since surcharges would not be in
effect on weekends.
                                  103

-------
                 TABLE 30

        RECURRING REVENUE CASH FLOW
                  ($000)

Cost
Revenue
Net Flow
Local
Gov't.
11,044
315,917
+304,873
State
Gov't.
20,183
-
-20,183
Federal
Gov't.
787
-
-787
Industry
424
33,624
+33,200
Citizen
384,911
67,808
-317,103
Total
417,349
417,349
—
                 TABLE 31

RECURRING REVENUE CASH FLOW MODIFIED BY THE
ELIMINATION OF MASS TRANSIT INCENTIVES AND
             PARKING SURCHARGE
                  ($000)

Cost
Revenue
Net Flow
Local
Gov't.
5,604
-
-5,604
State
Gov't.
20,183
-
-20,183
Federal
Gov't.
787
-
-787
Industry
424
33,624
+33,200
Citizen
33,892
27,266
-6,626
Total
60,890
60,890
—
                 104

-------
                 TABLE 32




IMPACT OF STRATEGIES UPON FUEL CONSUMPTION

Gasoline ($0.40 per gallon)
Stationary Vapor Control
Vehicle Retrofit
VMT Reduction
Total
Diesel ($0.15 per gallon)
200 Additional Buses
Fuel Saved
(600 gal.)

2,750
(15,375)
58,056
45,431
Fuel Increase
1,508
Savings
($000)

1,100
(6,150)
23,222
18,172
Cost
226
                105

-------
                       IV.   IMPACT OF STRATEGIES
     Under the Clean Air Act Amendments of 1970, EPA was directed to set
national air quality standards which would protect the public health and
welfare from the known effects of the major air pollutants.

     At the regional, state and local levels, institutional  arrangements
are being modified in order to deal with those air quality programs which
cross jurisdictional boundaries.  New arrangements have been found
necessary for completing the process of planning a program for a given
AQCR.  It can be anticipated that even more effective organizational and
budget arrangements will be required when the individual differences,
which will always occur because of the different impacts on  certain
interest and user groups within a given community, come into conflict.
The degree of acceptance or rejection of a given measure will eventually
be determined by the cumulative positions of the various individuals
affected.  It is extremely difficult to evaluate the overall effects of
measures where divergent views could be expected from what would normally
be considered homogeneous and predictable.  For example, certain measures
are expected to be unpopular with the business community. Yet, due to
the creation of a new product, service, or other economic feature, that
same measure could generate strong positive support from selected portions
of the same community.  Positive and negative interest groups can be
described in a scenario of every measure.

     The lack of predictable reactions from individuals and  consumer groups
makes an authoritative summary statement of an impact on society extremely
difficult.  The data from studies of the transportation control measures
conducted by consultants and the government and from the overall implementa-
tion plans failed to produce a specific methodology for completing this
portion of the program assessment.  While several prior studies completed
in-depth surveys of selected consumer interests (e.g., parking costs, modal
choices) and other studies contained discussions of the relevant social and
socioeconomic topics, no completed evaluation tools or decision matrices
designed to assist in the process of characterizing each measure in relation
to specific interest groups and issues were found.  An initial non-quantita-
tive but structured review process appears to be appropriate as a decision
tool that could be utilized by public administrators, task forces and public
interest citizen groups engaged in formulating implementation measures
and strategies acceptable to that particular community.  The process might
be most suitable for presentation in a public forum.

     For purposes of demonstrating the methodology and for completing a
study consensus, each measure has been evaluated by each study team member
on the basis of expected preference or perception by the majority of
involved San Diego individuals or interest groups.

     Figure 4 is a matrix developed to show the results of that attempt to
evaluate the overall program strategies from the point of view of a selected
number of specific consumer and societal interest groups and issues.  Where
                                  106

-------
STRATEGIES
STATIONARY SOURCES
VAPOR CONTROL
MOBILE SOURCES
CATALYST RETROFIT
OTHER HARDWARE
INSPECTION AND MAINTENANCE
MOTORCYCLE
V.M.T. REDUCTION
BUS/CAR-POOL LANES
BUS/CAR POOLS
PARKING SUPPLY
MASS TRANSIT
PARKING SURCHARGE
AIR QUALITY MONITORING (V.M.T.)
BICYCLE PATHS
FOUR-DAY WEEK
GASOLINE RATIONING
OTHER
AIRCRAFT
0
0
0
0
0
+
+
—
+
0
0
0
+
—
0
0
—
—
—
0
0
0
—
0
—
0
0
+
—
0
0
0
0
—
0
0
0
0
—
0
0
0
+
—
0
+
—
—
+
—
+
+
+
+
+
0
+
-t-
+
+
+
+
+
0
0
+
+
+
+
—
+
+
+
—
+
0
+
+
0
0
+
+
—
+
—
-f
0
—
—
0
0
/
/
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
/
0
•
0
0
/
/
/
./
/
/
•/
/
/
/
0
/
                    FIGURE 4:  STRATEGIES
                           107

-------
a favorable reaction was indicated by or for a majority, a "+" symbol
was used; a "-" indicates an unfavorable reaction; and a "0" indicates
no major impact, no clear preference, or an equally divided interest
without a major unfavorable impact on the specific groups affected.   For
purposes of this analysis, future strategies and program implementation
were considered on the basis of existing financial, tax, and economic
practices and policies.

     For most measures involving specific and direct impacts on individual
groups, a consensus of the majority position could be expected to be
reached through sufficient discussion and sampling.  However, in the
event that it is necessary to apply generally unpopular measures to
achieve necessary standards (e.g., the surcharge) an attempt to gain
consensus would be impractical.

     An interesting item noted during reporting of this analysis is that
11 of 15 of the measures, or 73 percent, are believed to have a positive
impact on the energy situation and would produce substantial fuel savings.
The results of certain measures, such as the four-day work week, are
difficult to determine using present methods and require further research
of the programs in cities such as Atlanta or in the over 4,000 corporations
and agencies reported to have implemented various test and trial programs.
                                  108

-------
                      V.  PROGRAM IMPLEMENTATION
     Based on the urban air quality data collected since 1969, Environ-
mental Protection Agency reports indicate that approximately 29 Air
Quality Control Regions encompassing major population centers will be
unable to achieve adequate emission reductions through the control of
stationary sources alone.

     The corrective measures and modifications required to meet projected
standards have been outlined.  Recent legislative modifications to imple-
mentation plans have resulted in a reduction of some of the immediate
pressures for compliance.  However, regardless of scheduled modifications
it appears that there will be a^ significant long-range socioeconomic        /"
impact upon our present life style^including"changes on~the automobile
dependency, industrial development, and land-use patterns.

     During PMM&Co.'s study of the San Diego implementation plan, an organiza-
tional modification, resulting in an institutional rearrangement was
announced as the future representative air pollution control task force
for the area.  A primary reason for this modification was the need to ensure
that all interest groups and jurisdictions representing the public interest
were fully represented in future program decisions regarding implementation.
A study of the institutional arrangements in the San Diego AQCR revealed that:

        a number of such adjustments have been necessitated by the
        program;

        such adjustments are representative of the environmental
        management challenges that exist at the state and regional
        levels; and

        these adjustments reflect the problems, common concerns, and
        individual differences relative to physical boundaries and air
        sheds.

     When one considers the magnitude of the management problem, it must be
recognized there are approximately 100 AQCRs and that approximately 29 of
these will require substantial air pollution control programs.  In addition,
all of the states have been required to submit state implementation plans
(SIP's) to EPA.  The agency has the authority and responsibility to modify
those plans determined to be inadequate to comply with the Clean Air Act.
In addition, the agency has the responsibility for outlining the procedures,
monitoring implementation, and determining the progress of the nation's air
pollution control program.

     The Environmental Protection Agency has recently initiated some studies
of the methodology and criteria which might be applied in establishing a
mechanism to assist and evaluate regions and states.  However, there has been
                                   109

-------
little indication of longer-range planning to overcome the substantial
technical difficulties and to identify financial resources which might be
required for air pollution control program management and implementation
during the next decade.

     Technical, legislative, financial, and social issues are involved in
the development of a system which transcends jurisdictional and political
interests and affects the daily living habits of the citizen.  At the present
time, certain standards and measures are sufficiently established and little
technical disagreement exist.  In some cases, measures have been partially
or fully implemented.  Overall, the program appears to be maturing to the
point where major decisions with regard to implementation management must
be made.  For example, the methods of sharing costs and of making program
decisions when there are differences among the jurisdictions must be
developed so that an orderly program implementation process can continue
while discussions and solutions of differences are carried out.  In addition,
where implementation of certain measures favor one jurisdiction over another,
a management process must be established where consensus can be reached.

     It is believed that the San Diego program has progressed to the point
where the active design of program, structures, procedures, and implementa-   /
tion methods for sharing both costs and (state and federal) assistance      L
should be developed.  In addition, the concurrent efforts of the San Diego
AQCR, the state of California, and the region should be supported in dev-
eloping an initial fully implemented air quality control reporting system.
Once a feasible system has been outlined and is operating, an evaluation
can be conducted to assess the suitability of summary information.  Such an
assessment will help to determine if monetary requirements can be met.  It
is recommended that an additional similar pilot program be identified and
implemented in another independent region and state.
                                  110

-------
                       BIBLIOGRAPHY
Air Pollution:  Alternative Controls for the San Diego Air Basin;
County of  San Diego Air Pollution Task Force; November 12, 1973.

Air Quality Implementation Plan Development for Critical California
Regions;   Summary Report; TRW Transportation & Environmental Operations;
Redondo Beach, Calif.; Environmental Protection Agency: July 1973.

Alternative Regional Growth Forecasts/Population and Employment -
1975-1995;San Diego Comprehensive Planning Organization; May 1972.

Analysis of the Existing Trends Regional Development Alternative/A
Working Paper; San Diego Comprehensive Planning Organization; June
1973.

Application of the San Diego Transit Corporation for a Mass Transportation
Capital Improvement Grant under the Urban Mass Transportation Act of 1964.

Background Material on Public Hearings for Transportation Control Strategies;
Environmental Protection Agency; Washington, D. C.;1973

Bigelow, J. H., Goeller, B. F., and Petruschell, R. L. ; A Policy-
Oriented Urban Transportation Model; The Los Angeles Version; Rand
Corp. Santa Monica, Calif.; October 1973.

1970 Census Data by Census Tract (Income, Education, Employment,
Spanish-American Population; San Diego Comprehensive Planning Organiza-
tion: January 1973.

Centre City Transportation Study/Circulation Study; Office of the City
Engineer, Transportation Planning Section, City of San Diego; San Diego,
Calif.; February 1971.

Centre City Transportation Study/Satellite Parking; Office of the City
Engineer, Transportation Planning Section; City of San Diego; San
Diego, Calif.; February 1971.

Control Equipment for Hydrocarbon Vapors at Gasoline Service Stations;
San Diego County Air Pollution Control District; San Diego, Calif.;
September 1973.

Cost Effectiveness of Methods to Control Vehicle Refueling Emissions;
Refinery Management Services Co.; American Petroleum Institute;
April 1973

Cumulative Regulatory Effects on the Cost of Automotive Transportation
(RECAT) ; Ad Hoc Committee on the Cumulative Regulatory Effects on the
Cost of Automotive Transportation; Office of Science_and Technology;
February 28, 1972.
                                   Ill

-------
DeHaven,  and Woodfill; Cost and Effectiveness of Strategies for Reducing
Emissions from Fixed  Sources: The San Diego Air Basin, 1975; Rand Corp.;
Santa Monica, Calif.; October 1973.

Dorfman and Snow; Who Bears the cost of Pollution Control?/The Impact
on the Distribution of Income of Financing Federally Required Pollution
Control;  Council on Environmental Quality; Washington, D. C.; August 12,1973.

Economic  Impact Assessment of Alternative Transportation Control Strategies/
Part I Final Report; Stephen Sobotka & Co.; May 1973.

Environment Reporter; excerpt  pp. 494-507. The Bureau of National Affairs,
Inc.; July 1973.

Evaluating Transportation Controls to Reduce Motor Vehicle Emissions in
Major Metropolitan Areas;Institute of Public Administration, Teknekron,
Inc., & TRW, Inc.; National Technical Information Service; Springfield,
Va.; November 1972.

Evaluation of EPA's Proposed Air Pollution Control Plan with Alternatives;
County of  San Diego Air Pollution Task Force; August 1973.

Goeller,  B. F., Bigelow, J. H. DeHaven, J.C., Mikolowsky, W. T.,
Petruschell, R. L., Woodfill, B. M., and McFarland, H. W.; San Diego
Clean Air  Project; Rand Corp.; Santa Monica, Calif.; July 1973.

Hocker, A. J.; Fifth Progress Report/Project CO/State Fleet Equipped
with UOP Device; Air Resources Board; El Monte, Calif.; August 1973.

Holmes, Horowitz, Reid, and Stolpman, The Clean Air Act and Transportation
Controls/An EPA White Paper; Environmental Protection Agency; Washington,
D. C.; August 1973.

Implementation of the Dimensional Logit Model, Peat, Marwick, Mitchell
ft Co.; (for San Diego County) Comprehensive Planning Organization;
Washington, D. C.; May 1972.

The Implications of Lead Removal from Automotive Fuel;Commerce Technical
Advisory Board Panel on Automotive Fuels and Air Pollution: U. S.
Department of Commerce; Washington, D. C.; June 1970

A Joint Effort for Clean Air in San Diego;Universal Oil Products Company;
Des Plaines, 111.; September 1973.

Kooner and Grant; San Diego Transit Corporation Operations Analysis; Office
of Regional Transportation and Land Use Programs, Environmental Development
Agency, County of San Diego; San Diego, Calif. September 1973.

Lonergan; Financial Report for the Year Ended June 30,. 1972; Office of
City Auditor and Comptroller, San Diego, Calif.; 1972.

Lonergan; Financial Report for the Year Ended June 30, 1973; Office of
City Auditor and Comptroller; San Diego, Calif.; 1973.
                                  112

-------
Merenda and  Kuhrtz;  Control Strategies for In-Use Vehicles; U. S.
Environmental Protection Agency; Washington, D. C.; November 1972.

Mikolowsky:   The Motor Vehicle Emission and Cost Model (MOVEC):  Model
Description  and Illustrative Applications; Rand Corp.: Santa Monica,
Calif.;  October 1973.

Polygon Information  Overlay System;San Diego Comprehensive Planning
Organization;  September 1971.

Prediction of  the Effects of Transportation Controls on Air Quality
in Major Metropolitan Areas; TRW, Inc.; McLean, Virginia; November 1972.

Progress Report on Implementation of the Dimensional Logit Model;
Peat, Marwick, Mitchell & Co.; for San Diego County, Comprehensive
Planning Organization, Washington, D. C.; September 1973.

The Regional Model System and the Planning/Decision Making Process;
A Non-Technical Description; San Diego Comprehensive Planning Organization;
April,  1972.

Rules and  Regulations/Air Pollution Control District; Revised Edition;
County  of  San Diego Department of Public Health; February 1972.

"Rules  and Regulations"; Federal Register; Vol. 38, No. 217, Environmental
Protection Agency; Nov. 12, 1973; pp. 31232-31255.

Sage, W. G.; The City of San Diego Annual Financial Report - Fiscal 1973;
Office of  City Auditor and Comptroller; San Diego, Calif.; 1973.

San Diego  Transit Corporation SB-325 Application FT 1973-74; March 1973.

Sauter,  G. D. and Ott, W. R.; "A Computer Program for Projections of
Vehicular  Pollutant Emissions in Urban Areas"; Journal of the Air Pollution
Control  Association, Vol. 24 No. 1; January 1974, pp. 54-59.

Schwartz,  S. I.; "Reducing Air Pollution by Automobile Inspection and
Maintenance: A Program Analysis"; Journal of the Air Pollution Control
Association, Vol.  23, No. 10; October 1973; pp. 845-852.

Semiannual Report; The Committee on Motor Vehicle Emissions of the National
Academy  of Sciences;  Washington, D. C.; January 1972.

Socio-Economic Impacts of the Proposed State Transportation Control Plans;
An Overview; Transportation & Environmental Operations; Redondo Beach,
Calif.;  August 1973.

The State  of California Implementation Plan for Achieving and Maintaining
the National Ambient Air Quality Standards; Revision 3;  The California
Air Resources Board; June 1973.
                                    113

-------
The  State  of  California Implementation Plan for Achieving and Maintaining
the  National  Ambient Air Quality Standards; The California Air Resources
Board,  January  1972.

System  Development for Modeling the Relationship Between Land-Use and
Air  Quality in  San Diego County; Transportation & Environmental Operations
of,TRW, Inc., Redondo Beach, Calif.; August 1973.

Taylor;  Candidate Transportation Systems;San Diego County Comprehensive
Planning Organization; December 1971.

Taylor,  Hayden, Sloop, LaRosa; Air Pollution;  Alternative Controls for
the  San Diego Air Basin;San Diego, Calif.; November 1973.

Technical  Support Document for the San Diego Intrastate Air Quality
Control Region; Environmental Protection Agency, Region IX: San
Francisco, Calif. July 31, 1973.

Transit Development Plan & Program Fiscal Year 1972-1973 Update; San
Diego Comprehensive Planning Organization; May 1973.

Transit Development Plan & Program;Alan M. Voorhees & Associates, Inc.;
for  San Diego Comprehensive Planning Organization; June 1970.

Transportation Control Strategy Development for the Metropolitan Los
Angeles  Angeles Region; TRW Transportation & Environmental Operations;
Redondo  Beach, Calif.; Environmental Protection Agency; December 1972.

Watkins, Borden, Kirchner; Highway Research Report/Can Vehicle Travel
be Reduced 20 Percent in the California South Coast Basin?; Sacramento,
Calif.;  January, 1974.

Weiner,  Edward; DOT-EPA Technical Conference on Air Quality Analysis/
Techniques Needed for Better Air Quality Analysis; Office of The
Secretary of  Transportation; Washington, D. C., May 1973

We're Going Your Way I San Diego Transit Corporation; San Diego, Calif.;
July 1973.

Winkler; Transportation Control Strategy Development for the Denver
Metropolitan Area; Springfield, Va.; December 1972.

Winkler: Transportation Control Strategies for the State Implementation
Plan City of  Philadelphia; National Technical Information Service;
Springfield,  Va.; December 1972.
                                114

-------
       APPENDIX A




DESCRIPTION OF SAN DIEGO




    MODAL SPLIT MODEL

-------
                                Appendix A

                DESCRIPTION OF SAN DIEGO MODAL SPLIT MODEL
SELECTION OF THE n-DIMENSIONAL LOGIT MODEL

Two factors governed the selection of the n-Dimensional Logit Model (logit
model) for implementation in San Diego:  (1) the sparsity of transit data;
and (2) the desire to simultaneously evaluate traveler choices among three
modes — transit passenger, automobile driver, and automobile passenger.
Development of a modal split model requires data describing travel by each
of the alternative modes.  The principal source of this data for the San
Diego region is the 1966 Home Interview Survey.  Inasmuch as a uniform sample
of households was surveyed, and because only about four percent of the home-
to-work travel used transit, only a small number of transit users are in the
sample.

Previous efforts to model modal splits have encountered difficulties because
they required an estimate of the proportion of travelers using transit.  To
obtain accurate estimates of an observed modal split, analysts were obliged
to aggregate data.  This solution resulted, however, in a significant
reduction in the detail — and thus the meaning — of the transportation
service and socioeconomic measures used to predict modal split.  These
problems are not encountered by the logit model, since it is developed using
data describing the travel mode choice of individual travelers.  In San Diego,
development of the models used all of the valid recorded transit trips in
the region without recourse to aggregation.

It is desirable to simultaneously estimate transit use and automobile
occupancy, inasmuch as these are interrelated phenomena.  A key problem with
previously established modal choice models is that they are limited to binary
choices (i.e., a choice between only two alternatives).  Analysts have
generally attempted to surmount the limitations imposed by a binary choice
model by using a step-wise or staged approach for estimating splits between
one mode and "all other," and repeating the procedure as necessary.  This
step-wise approach obliges the analyst to use aggregate modal service
measures for the initial steps of the process, which often requires
arbitrary decisions regarding, for example, weighted or arithmetic averages.
This artificial, staged analysis inherently implies the risks of error
propagation.  For these reasons, San Diego requires a modal split model
capable of simultaneously estimating traveler choices selected from the
three available options — transit passenger, automobile driver, and auto-
mobile passenger.

STRUCTURE OF THE n-DIMENSIONAL LOGIT MODEL

In the selection of a suitable structure for a multi-mode modal split model,
several properties are required:
                                    A-l

-------
        the sum of the modal shares should equal one;

        a given mode's share (i.e., percent traveling by mode) decreases
        with increasing levels of that mode's service measures (e.g.,
        time); and

        the shares of other modes increase with increases in the given
        mode's service measures. -

These theoretical considerations lead to the formulation of the n-dimen-
sional logit model.

In the logit model, the modal split of a given mode m is given by

                   exp( I «x   + «)
            w
             m    2 exp( 2 a..x..  + a.)
                             3       J
where:
     .  x.. is the i   impedance attribute of mode j (e.g., transit

        in-vehicle time);

        ex.. is the calibrated coefficient corresponding to x..; and

        or. is a calibrated mode-specific constant.

This formulation does not require that the same set of variables be used to
define the transportation attributes of each of the modes.  Further, the
above formulation can be shown to hold when some of the x's, in fact, are
socioeconomic variables, such as income.

IMPLEMENTATION OF THE n-DIMENSIONAL LOGIT MODEL
  IN SAN DIEGO

Based on careful review of the CPO's requirements, the capabilities of the
logit model, and the characteristics of the calibration data, it was concluded
that the logit model should be used to predict the modal choice among the
basic alternatives of transit passenger, automobile driver and automobile
passenger.  The model defines the choice of mode as a function of several
independent variables which describe the characteristics of the transporta-
tion system, the traveler, and the trip.  Selection of the independent
variables to be used in the model was constrained by the availability of
forecasts for these variables.  Consequently, it was not possible to
incorporate such socioeconomic variables as the age, sex., or education of
the traveler within the modal split model, since detailed forecasts of these
variables are not available from the Protective Land-Use Model (PLUM) being
developed for CPO.  The transportation system variables used to characterize
automobile travel are in- and out-of-vehicle times, and operating and parking

                                   A-2

-------
costs.  Similar variables are used to describe transit service; these are
walking times  Cat both ends), in-vehicle, waiting, and transfer times,
and transit fare.  Socioeconomic variables that were considered included
household income and automobile ownership, variables for which forecasts
are available.

A calibration  sample that fulfilled all of the following criteria was
extracted from the 1966 Home Interview Survey.  In order to qualify for
the the sample an entry had to:

        include travel from home-to-work (work-to-home trips were
        not considered);

        take place during morning travel period (5:00 a.m. to 10:00 a.m.);

        have origins and destinations in the area served by transit;

        utilize one of the following modes - automobile driver, automobile
        passenger, or transit passenger;

        contain valid responses to the income questions; and

        involve interzonal travel.

The calibration data set was stratified into two sets:  travel to the
Central Business District (CBD) and travel to non-CBD destinations.  This
stratification was selected because investigations indicated that the
propensity to  use transit for CBD travel was greater for equivalent service
alternatives than it was for non-CBD travel.  Characteristics of the CBD
and non-CBD data sets are presented in Figure A-l; these samples contain
809 and 3,109  observations, respectively.

A search process was undertaken to select that set of independent variables
which provide  the best modal split models for the San Diego region.  The
recommended CBD and non-CBD models are presented in Figure A-2.  Three
transportation variables, the differences in line-haul time, excess time,
modal costs, and one socioeconomic variable, household income, are used in
the recommended models.  All of the coefficients in the recommended models
are significant at the 95 percent level.

The major contrast between the CBD and non-CBD models is found in the time
and cost coefficients c, d, and e.  For the  (BD model, the effect of excess
time as compared to line-haul time (i.e., ratio of c/d) is about 1.63.  The
derived value  of time (i.e., the ratio of e to c or d) is $3.18/hour for
line-haul time and $5.17/hour for excess time.  These estimates confirm
results observed elsewhere.  Excess time becomes a critical determinant of
modal choice for non-CBD trips as shown by the value of Coefficient c and
the weight of  excess time (relative to line-haul time), both of which are
substantially  higher than in the CBD model.  The increase in the weight
of excess time from 1.6 to 6.8 reflects both the major differences in CBD
and non-CBD transit service and the differences in travel behavior resulting


                                   A-3

-------
                                                 Mean Values
Trip Characteristics






Auto Drivers




Auto Passengers




Transit Passengers




Income Level




Auto Network Access Time




Auto Terminal Time




Total Auto Time




Auto Travel Time




Auto Distance




Auto Parking Cost




Walk-to-Transit Time




Transit Vehicle Time




Transit Wait Time




Transit Transfer Time




Total Transit Time




Transit Fare
       CBD
570 trips (70.5%)




174 trips (21.5%)




 65 trips ( 8.0%)




    $9-10,000




     0.8 minutes




     4.6 minutes




    17.8 minutes




    12.3 minutes




     7.7 miles




      47 cents




     8.3 minutes




    29.8 minutes




    13.0 minutes




     6.0 minutes




    57.1 minutes




      44 cents
     Non-CBD






2610 trips (83.9%)




 406 trips (13.1%)




  93 trips ( 3.0%)




     $9-10,000




      1.7 minutes




      2.3 minutes




     11.6 minutes




     15.7 minutes




      7 .1 miles




      0.0 cents




     10.4 minutes




     30.8 minutes




     13.7 minutes




     11.4 minutes




     66.3 minutes




     47.4 cents
                                FIGURE A-l:




                 CHARACTERISTICS OF CALIBRATION DATA SETS

-------
Model Form:
Po =
                            1.0
 p   1.0 + exp(aT!35 + b) + exp(cDx3 + dD13 + eDCH + f)
PD
                     expJaT135 + b)
     1.0 + exp(aT!35 + b) + exp(cDX3 + dD13 + eDCH + f)
pT = 	exp(cDX3 + dDL3 + eDCH = f)	
     1.0 + exp(aT!35 + b) + exp(cDX3 + dDL3 + eDCH + f)
                                                            Parameters  of  the Models:
Parameter
a
b
c
d
e
f
CBD Model
0.0295
-1.4809
0.0916
0.0563
0.0106
1.1635
Non-CBD Model
0.0268
-0.5441
0.1314
0.0192
0.0184
1.6600
Nomenclature :
V PD» 1

exp

a, b, c,
d, e, f

TI35
 INC

 DX3


 DL3


 DCH
= auto passenger, auto driver, and transit passenger modal choice probabilities

= exponential operator

= calibrated coefficients and constants for the model


= transformed household income
= 100(l-exp(-0.035*INC))

= household income in hundreds of dollars

= difference in excess time
= walk to/from auto time - (walk to transit time + first wait for transit + walk from transit)

= difference in line haul time
= auto driving time - (transit in vehicle time + transit transfer time)

= difference in modal cost
  auto operating cost (5p/mile) + half of parking cost - transit fare

                                   FIGURE A-2:

                          SAN DIEGO MODAL SPLIT MODELS

-------
 therefrom.

 The recommended models were tested to see if they could reproduce the
 total number of automobile passenger, automobile driver, and transit
 passenger trips in the calibration sample.  The recommended CBD and non-
 CBD models reproduce almost exactly the total number of trips in each of
 the three modes considered.  The calculated trips were within a (negligible)
 fraction of one percent of the observed trips.

 A further test of the recommended -model is its ability to reproduce the
 observed trip distributions by trip length for each of the three modes under
 consideration.  The cumulative distributions of transit trips as a function
 of trip length (in minutes) as observed in the calibration data set and
 estimated by the model are presented in Figure A-3.  In all trip length
 ranges, the calculated distribution of transit passengers is within about
 15 percent or less of the observed distribution.  The accuracy of these
 results is indicative of the overall quality of the recommended models.

 TESTING OF THE SAN DIEGO MODEL IN SAN FRANCISCO
  AND BOSTON

 The modal split models will be used to evaluate transit systems offering
 service which is significantly better than existing transit service.  Thus,
 there is a concern that the modal split model appropriately reflects consumer
 response to significantly improved service, (i.e., extended regions of the
 transit service variables).  Thus, the model was tested using extended ranges
 of transit service from two other metropolitan areas.  Validation analyses
 were performed for the Golden Gate corridor in the San Francisco metropolitan
 area and the Reading corridor in the Boston metropolitan area.

 Relative to San Diego, excellent public transportation service is provided
 in the Reading corridor by commuter railroad, rapid transit, and bus.  The
 difference between San Diego's and Boston's transit as compared to auto-
mobile service is evident in the difference in line-haul time; average transit
 line-haul time in Boston is six minutes less than automobile time, while it
 is  23 minutes  longer in San Diego.  On the other hand, transit is, relatively
 speaking, more expensive in Boston than in San Diego; the average cost
 difference (automobile - transit) is 14£ in Boston and 22<: in San Diego.

 The San Diego model applied to the Reading corridor data yielded an average
 transit modal split of 23.0 percent, compared to an observed share of 27.6
 percent.  The slight underestimation of transit modal split is ascribed to
 travelers in the Boston area having been "conditioned" to transit travel.
 The cumulative observed and calculated transit trip distributions were
 developed by automobile travel time, as shown in Figure A-4.  The distri-
 butions are very comparable and lend credence to the assumption that the
 under-reporting results from a general difference in behavior between Boston
 and San Diego travelers and not to systematic biases of Che San Diego model.
 The successful validation of the model with Boston data indicates that the
model can be used to evaluate the ridership and revenue resulting from a
 rail transit system in San Diego.
                                   A-6

-------
  60
w

H
PS
  40
  20
                  Observed


                               /
^—Calculate d
                          10


                         TIME
            15
20
                      FIGURE A-3:


      CUMULATIVE TIME DISTRIBUTION OF TRANSIT TRIPS

                    SAN DIEGO MODEL

-------
         100
I
oo
       -a
       PI

       g
            0
                         10
20
50
30          40

     TIME



 FIGURE A-A:
                                CUMULATIVE TIME DISTRIBUTION OF TRANSIT TRIPS

                                   SAN DIEGO MODEL APPLIED TO BOSTON DATA
>60

-------
The Golden Gate Bridge connects San Francisco to suburban Marin and Sonoma
Counties.  The average automobile travel time is over three times longer in
the Golden Gate corridor than it is in San Diego — 58 versus 18 minutes.
In contrast, the average transit travel time is only 150 percent longer in
the Golden Gate corridor than in San Diego - 85 versus 57 -minutes.   Thus,
in terms of the difference in line-haul time, the automobile is 23  minutes
faster in San Diego, whereas transit is two minutes faster in San Francisco.
Because of the higher parking costs in San Francisco Cabout $2.00 versus
$.45), the tolls for the Golden Gate Bridge, and the longer commuting
distances, average automobile costs are much higher in San Francisco than
San Diego.  Thus, whereas transit is 22
-------
Transit (%)
Auto
Average CBD Modal Splits (%)
Relative Changes (%)






>
1
o
Excess Line-Haul Parking
Time Time Fare Cost
—
+20
+20 — -- +25
+25
+20 — +25
-10 -20
-10 -20 +25
-10 -20 +25 +25
Auto Auto
Drivers Passengers
70.45
72.01
71.66
70.01
72.38
67.49
68.70
68.15
21.51
22.02
21.91
21.37
22.15
20.54
20.93
20.76
Transit
Passengers
8.04
5.97
6.42
8.62
5.47
11.97
10.37
11.09
Auto
Drivers
—
+2.21
+1.17
-0.62
+2.74
-4.20
-2.48
-3.26
Auto
Passengers
+2.37
+1.86
-0.65
+2.98
-4.51
-2.70
-3.49
Transit
Passengers
-25.75
-20.15
+7.21
-31.97
'•48.88
+28.98
+37 . 94
                                            FIGURE A-5:




                                    SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS OF MODEL

-------
The elasticities of the average modal split estimated for the CBD sample
were determined.  Transit modal split is elastic with respect to transit
excess and line-haul times and the difference in access time.  In other
words, a one percent relative increase in any of these variables results
in a greater relative decrease in transit modal split.  Transit fare,
however, is inelastic:  a one percent increase in transit fare results in
a one-third of one percent decrease in transit ridership in the area served
by transit in San Diego.  A uniform 10 percent fare increase for each trip
would result in about a net three percent decrease in transit ridership.

CONCLUSION

A graph of the recommended CBD model displaying transit modal split as
a function of the difference of excess times for several levels of cost
and line-haul travel time differences (DC and DL respectively) is presented
in Figure A-6.  This graph can be used to rapidly estimate the order of
magnitude transit modal split associated with various combinations of
independent variables.  For example, for a $10,000 annual income and equal
service by both modes in terms of times and costs, transit's share would
be 46 percent of the market.  This result suggests that the low utilization
of transit in San Diego in 1966 was due to the relatively low quality of the
transit service, not to a systematic automobile bias.

The difficulty of improving the quality of transit service in San Diego
should not be underestimated.  In 1966, the average difference in excess
time for all travelers destined to the CBD was -17 minutes (i.e., the
excess time for automobile was 17 minutes less than the excess time for
transit), the average difference in line-haul times was -23 minutes, while
the average difference in cost was -fl8
-------
>
i
                                           100
                 HOUSEHOL
                 	 DIFF
                 	DIFF
)  INCOME =
RENCE IN
RENCE IN
 $10,000
:OST=
:OST= o
                                            80
                                                  TRANSIT
                                                MODAL SPLIT
                                                          DL = -30
DL = 15
                                                          DL =  0
                                 DL = -15
                                      X
                                       x-
                         •10        -5          0         5         10

                         DIFFERENCE IN EXCESS TIME (AUTO-TRANSIT)


                                            FIGURE A-6:


                                       GRAPH OF SAN DIEGO MODEL

-------
Because it specifically addresses multiple choice situations, the logit
model developed for San Diego allows transit usage and "automobile occupancy"
to be simultaneously analyzed.  This multi-modal capability offers great
promise for transit planning, inasmuch as the-model correctly incorporates
the competition among the combinations of transit submodes (rail rapid and
all-bus) and access modes (feeder bus, park-and-ride, kiss-and-ride,  and
walk) and the automobile submodes (automobile driver and passenger).

The calibrated model very accurately reproduced the total number of observed
automobile passengers, automobile drivers, and transit passengers.  In
addition, the model reproduced very well the aggregate modal splits observed
in two other cities for extended ranges of the transit service variables.
This result is most encouraging since transit in Boston and San Francisco
consists of express-bus and rapid rail services not yet available in San
Diego.  Overall, these results support the validity of using the developed
logit model as a planning tool for evaluating higher quality transit services
than are currently available in the San Diego region.
                                   A-13

-------
                 APPENDIX B
REVIEW AND ASSESSMENT OF TRAVEL DEMAND MODELS

-------
                              APPENDIX B

              REVIEW AND ASSESSMENT OF TRAVEL DEMAND MODELS


In order to analyze the travel impacts of the EPA promulgated plan,  it was
necessary to incorporate an approach capable of relating the demand  for
automobile travel to the price of automobile travel.  A literature search
revealed the following travel demand models as approaches for achieving
this objective:

     *  Demand Generator and Modal Split Model — Rand Corp.;

     •  Direct Demand Estimation Model — Kraft:

        Attitudinal Model — Wallace;

        Shopping Trip Frequency Model — Charles River Associates; and

        Econometric Model of Gasoline Consumption — Data Resources, Inc.

Appendix B provides a review and assessment of these approaches.

DEMAND GENERATOR AM) MODAL SPLIT MODEL - RAND

A demand generator and modal split model was developed in 1973 by the Rand
Corporation for evaluating various environmental control policies in the
Los Angeles metropolitan area.  To that end, its builders attempted to
avoid the conventional Urban Transportation Planning process (UTP) involving
large data requirements, cumbersome zonal systems and networks, excessive
human and computer resources, decomposition of a complex and probably
simultaneous process into a set of consecutive steps — to name only a few
of the shortcomings of the UTP process.  To say that they achieved such an
ambitious aim which has eluded both planning researchers and practitioners
in the past 20 years is a Rubicon which a skeptic would not cross without
some hesitation, (whatever the temptation!).

Overview of the Model

The modeling approach has three major features:  it does not rely on a
zonal system, it combines demand and modal split in one step, and it takes
account of foregone trips.  The model generates aggregate numbers of the
persons trips, vehicle-miles, passenger-miles and vehicle occupancies broken
down by mode, purpose and time of day.  To this end, it assumes as given
a "conventional" forecast of total travel by bus and automobile in what the
authors call the "nominal" case.  Also assumed as given is the limit of the
total number of trips which would be made regardless of the service level
of the available modes.  Foregone trips are then defined as the difference
between the total trips which would be made and the trips actually made.
For any given transportation policy, modal as well as foregone trips would change
while the total number of trips remains constant.  Trips are divided into essential
                               B-l

-------
trips and inessential trips.  This distinction applies to inessential trips
inasmuch as there are no essential trips foregone.

Mathematically, the above is expressed as follows:

                          T* 4- T* + T* = T
                           A    B    F

                          T  + T  + T  = T
                           A    B    F

where T^, Tg, Tp, and T are respectively the total number of automobile
trips, bus trips, foregone trips and total limiting or "saturating" trips,
and where the asterick denotes the nominal case.

The transportation system variables are combined into a conductance function
(to be defined later) so that for each mode the change in trips resulting
from a given policy must be in proportion to the ratio of their conductances,
namely

                              X*"  ~   VJ*
                               A       A
                                       B
                              Tl
where 9 is a proportionality factor, W represents conductances and the
subscipts A, B, and F denote automobile, bus and foregone trips, respectively.
The conductances of foregone trips is set equal to 1.

The conductances of each mode are postulated to be a function of excess
time XT, line-haul time LT and travel cost C (mileage plus parking or fare)
which are combined into a disutility or unattractiveness U.  The form of
the function U is derived from the Utilitarian Modal Split model developed
by Alan M. Vorhees and Associates, namely

                          U = 2.5 X T 4- LT + C/0.25 I

I being the average traveler income.  For trips of given length D, line-haul
times by automobile and bus, are derived from speeds and a street mix
usage function which was derived experimentally.  As will be discussed later,
automobile occupancies are taken into account as a function of distance
for estimating costs.
                                   B-2

-------
The model is based on two additional assumptions.  First, the trip length
distribution function f (D)  is  assumed known.  Second, the conductance
function of each mode follows a logit structure.  Mathematically, the
number of essential trips by mode m is given by
/

                             -
                  T   -  T        m Tm f (D)  dD
                   m      e
•a  T*
Tn  m
where Te is the total number of essential trips, and where the conductance
WH! of a given mode m is defined by

                         TT         U* (D)
                         WEI  =  exp  m
                               exp Um (D)

Similar equations are also presented for estimating passenger-miles and
vehicle-miles.  The integrations over D are performed numerically from 0
to 50 miles by one-half-mile increments.

For inessential trips, occupancy is assumed to remain constant for a given
trip purpose.  A function r(D) of trip length is postulated to describe
the attractiveness of potential destinations which is assumed to increase,
reach a peak, and decrease.  In fact, the function used has a horizontal
asymptote, namely

                                  KQ D
                          T(D) =  ——
where K^ was determined so that the average of T matches the average trip
length and KQ so that/*50            Whence, the conductance function:
                     /     T(D)  =  1.

                      0                               W   «= T(D)   exp  [u*(  D)]
                                                      m           exp  [U  (D)]

The number of inessential  trips by mode m  (i.e., bus, automobile  or foregone
trips) is given by the same inegration process as for essential trips, namely
                                 m.
                        Tm        '
                         m  =  —=-
                                 m
                                    m
where T is the number of "saturating"trips and where «/D       for foregone
trips.  It should be noted that if  T(D) is interpreted as a trip length
distribution function — which in fact it appears to be — then there is
no structural difference in the treatment of essential and inessential
trips except as far as foregone trips are concerned.

The modeling approach lends itself to breaking down trips into peak
and off-peak periods as well as bus-eligible and non-bus-eligible areas.
                                  B-3

-------
 As mentioned earlier automobile occupancy was  specifically introduced
 into the analysis process,  in particular  for essential  trips where it
 was supposed to vary as function of  trip  length  instead of remaining
 constant as for inessential trips.   This  is done by first estimating the
 delay experienced by a potential carpooler as           	
                                               ALT =   flOD exp  (.5 I)  )
                                                      \~"p~    •  \  10 i

 where  is  a calibrated parameter,  P  the density of residents living near
 the potential carpooler, and D the trip length.  Then,  for a car pool of
 size n the  average delay experienced by a member is given by
                                                    >
                            ALT  = (n-1)  ALT
                               n

 to which corresponds a distance penalty AD derived from ALT  by assuming
 a  speed of  15 mph.

 Average occupancy is then determined for  a given distance D so that, given
 a  parametrically expressed  proportion!^  of people in cars of occupancy n,
 the unattractiveness of essential trips averaged over all carpool sizes
 is minimized.   The proportion Ha of  people in  cars of occupancy n is taken
 to be
                                    n-1
where % is the positive parameter determined by minimizing the average
unattractiveness for a trip of length D.  The resulting average occupancy
is given by

                                   I [-
                        0(D)  »   n=l
Comments

According to its authors, the Rand transportation model is a "much needed
flexible policy oriented tool for evaluating alternative transportation
management stratagies."  Presently, there is no generally accepted and truly
satisfactory model available to provide information to policy makers.  In
reviewing and evaluating Rand's work, two basic and interrelated questions
come to mind.  First, what information and what level of detail does it offer?
Second, on what theoretical foundations is the model built and how well does
it reproduce the phenomena it addresses?  The model essentially estimates,
from transportation service and cost levels, total travel demand at
a regional level.  This travel demand is broken down by mode, including so-
called foregone trips, by vehicle-miles and passenger-miles, as well as by
                                     B-4

-------
peak and off-peak periods.  Concurrently, it estimates various other  derived
measures, such as, average automobile occupancy and bus loads, average trip
lengths by mode and so forth.

These data are obviously of interest to policy-making but only at a very
"macro" level.  There is no information as to how major subareas of the
region or its various population strata are affected.  This is so because
of the modeling structure used by Rand.

The authors claim that the modeling framework they developed is simultaneous
and leaves aside the stepwise UTP approach.  Unfortunately, this is strictly
speaking not the case:  their approach is also stepwise inasmuch as T* and
T, the nominal and saturating trip levels are exogeneous to the model.
Even worse, the inputs are provided by conventional studies.  The assertion
that the model is not a forecasting tool is "puzzling", not to say dubious:
the policy-maker seeks information on the consequences of policies which are
not yet implemented, a process which is by definition a forecast.  It jnight
be a short-term forecast but it often deals, as is the case of pollution
control policies, with conditions which can be drastically different from
the nominal case.

Rand has imbedded in its approach the notion of conductance which has been
used with little success in intercity demand/modal split modeling without
a formal constraint on the total number of  trips  (the PML model  and  the
Composite Analytic model which incidentally was a simultaneous model).  It
also relies on previous work in a cumbersome way by  combining a  logit model
with the "Utilitarian" modal split model in a rather obscure  fashion.   The
disutility or unattractiveness function used has not been  calibrated;  it
has been "postulated" from empirical experience and  then a  "curve was
drawn."  Had  it been formally estimated, the model would be called a probit
model.  One wonders why mention the logit model which is essentially a
disaggregate model within a  (very ) aggregate approach.  Further,  the  logit
or the probit model includes a constant  in  the difference  of  disutilities
inasmuch as  the absence of a constant  term would  imply that for  equal
disutility, modal choice would be equal  —  an implication  which  is true
if excess time, line-haul time and out-of-pocket  cost fully describe a mode.

The difference  in the integration process between essential and  inessential
trips is difficult  to explain.  There  is no structural difference  between
the treatment of  the  two  types of trips  if  one  considers,  as  mentioned_
earlier, the function T(D) as a trip  length distribution and  if  essential
trips foregone  set  equal  to  zero.  Essential trips by automobile (for
example) are calculated as:           -  I
                              TAT,  »  T-, I    F  [AU(D)]  f (D) dD
                               AE      b/_
            with                          *
                         F[AU(D)]  -     TAE WA(D)
                                         TAE VD) + TBE VD)


            which leads  to
                                         jQQ      .

                                                TAE WA(D)             f(D) dD

                                                TA*TT WA + TTfp WU(D>
                                                 AJb   A       Jj£»  D

                                         B-5

-------
However in the case of inessential trips, automobile trips are given by:

                                    T*/*  W.(D)
                      T '  -  f       J-0  A
                      XAI      XI -    ^
                                            IjC
                                             «/jj


instead of
                                               TBIC VD) + TFI
                                         T*W(D)
                                     T*  W.(D)  + 1
                                      A-L  A       £>j.  D       co.


two formulations which are not equivalent.

The modeling structure addresses  automobile occupancy  or carpooling in a
way which raises several questions.  It  is understandable that, individually,
"people use their cars so as to make them least unattractive."  But one
wonders if this remains true if people in the same trip length behave
similarly regardless of the trip destination, an  issue which the model
"ignores" totally.  Then for a given distance an  average occupancy is
derived for a given distance.  How would such an  average figure be used
for testing parking policies advocating  free parking for groups of three
of more people in a car or, generally speaking, setting parking prices
as a function of automobile occupancy?

The authors propose a formulation of  the distribution  of people in cars
as follows:                     _
                 IIn =	x11"1	 (1 £ n £ 6)
                      1 •»• x + x2 4- x3 + x4 + x5

This formulation implies that if x is less than 1,  the proportion of  cars
of occupancy equal to 1 is larger than  that of  occupancy equal to 2,  and
so forth.  If x  is greater than one,  the reverse is true.   There is no
mention in the report on how does x  vary when  distance varies. One would
doubt  that an occupancy of 6 is more likely than an occupancy  of, say,  2
or 3.  This could happen "inside" the computer program inasmuch as the
search for x(D)  is constrained by x  being  positive.

The estimation of the carpooling  time penalty  also  raises  several
questions.  This penalty is derived  from trip  length  distributxon for
work  trips and calculated  as            /
                               ATT =  A  /10.D
                               ALT =  9  /	   exp
 The use of the residential density p seems incompatible with a modeling
 structure which deliberately casts aside any zonal system and relies only
 on a trip length distribution function.  If p is considered constant, then
 it can be factored out and included in (J) .  If residential densities were
                                  B-6

-------
 used for one end of  the  trip,  it  appears  that employment densities
 would also be used inasmuch as carpooling opportunities hinge on both
 ends of a trip.   The description  of  the calibration method of the
 coefficient $ would  have been  of  interest, not to mention its numerical
 value.   No indication is given as to whether carpooling penalties are
 considered as excess time or line-haul time.  Finally, the term ALT
 represents a delay incurred by the driver to pick up "each of his riders."
 The  report states that the "average  delay experienced by a member" of a
 carpool of size  n is
This seems wrong as can be seen by considering a two-person carpool:  the
driver experiences a delay ALT and the rider no delay (as far as carpooling
is concerned).  Hence, an average delay of l/2ilLT instead of ALT as
predicted by the above formula.

The calibration question raised earlier applies to the entire report.  Very
little is said about this step which is very important in any modeling
exercise, especially in a case of new framework.  In a sens^e, the approach
suggested cannot be calibrated.  Many "borrowings" are necessary.  This
is very understandable but one would expect to learn more about the sen-
sitivity of the model.  Except for the discussion in an appendix to the
report, which is comewhat unconclusive and too general, there is little
said about this critical issue.  There are too many coefficients involved—
K!> Ko, <{> trip length distributions—not to address this issue.  In par-
ticular, what is the effect of very small levels of transit trips, es-
pecially for nonessential trips, in a metropolitan area such as Los Angeles?

The need for a modeling framework which is sensitive to policy variables,
"easy" to use and requiring little resources, is obvious.  The model
attempts to achieve these objectives and the reader would certainly welcome
such an achievement.  However, there are too many unanswered questions.
The lack of testing, as evidenced from the report, is unfortunate.  The
"transferability" of a model "calibrated" in so specific an area as Los
Angeles is not demonstrated.  There are theoretical contradictions which
seem to cast doubt, on the carpooling treatment in particular.   Nonetheless,
it is hoped that this approach, which has more merits than would appear
from a deliberately critical standpoint, may help improve the state-of-the-
art.

DIRECT DEMAND ESTIMATION MODELS - KRAFT

The Economic Demand Model developed by G. Kraft is typical of the simultaneous
generation/distribution/modal split models.  The model extends to urban trips
the work the author undertook in analyzing intercity trips.

The model derives its origin from economic theory which, according to Kraft,
provides useful guidelines for specifying a transportation demand model for
two broad reasons: it identifies the variables determining demand and
specifies the general nature of the relationship between demand and these
                                  B-7

-------
variables.  Briefly speaking, consumer behavior theory indicates that the
variables influencing demand for a given service are the price of this
service, the prices of the competing services and income.  Translated in
the  context of  travel demand, a mode has at least two "prices", travel
times and travel costs.  Economic theory indicates that demand for a given
mode should be  negatively related to its own prices and positively to the
prices of the competing modes.

Relevant socioeconomic variables include both the individuals and the
measures of output of the activities which attract trips inasmuch as
transportation  can be considered as a derived demand commodity.  In other
words, it is desired, not for its own sake, but to satisfy another
demand such as work, shopping or recreation.  Thus, trips are stratified
by purposes to each of which correspond special activities measured — e.g.,
employment for work trips.  It is assumed that generally demand is positively
related to income and activity measures.  Finally, as the model is set at
an aggregate leval, it is expected that aggregate demand will be positively
related to the population comprising the market, i.e., the zone of origin.
Finally, demand is expressed in round-trips generated at a given origin.
Among others, Kraft cites two reasons for this approach:  the traveler
considers time and cost conditions on both legs of the trip and the outbound
mode strongly influences the inbound mode.  The general functional form
adopted for the model is as follows :
                                                                 ,

                             C(t>3»i\P9,M  )]         •      •
where                        —        '  UJ a

" ' *•* j t i \Ptit MD)  - the number of round trips between origin i and destina
                     tion j for purpose Po by mode Mo,

        —   I  o/   = vector of socioeconomic characteristics appropriate
                     to purpose Po describing the travelers residing in
                     zone i,

                   = vector of socioeconomic and land-use characteristics
                     describing the level of activity appropriate to pur-
                     pose Po in destination zone j ,

                   ~ vector of travel time components for the round trip
                     from origin i to destination j for purpose PO by mode
 C(i) Jt i \PO^MQ) = vector of travel cost components for the round trip
                     cost components for the round trip between origin i
                     and destination j, for purpose Po by mode MQ,
                                   B-8

-------
 _< ljJj i \Po,M^J  - vector  of  travel  time  components for the round trip
                      between origin  i  and destination j, for purpose P0
                      by  each of the  alternative modes (a - l,...,n),

   C(i-, 3 ji\P * *M  J= vector  of  travel  cost  components for the round trip
   ~~                  between origin  i  and destination j for purpose P0 by
                      each of the alternative modes  (a = l,...,n).

Four  alternative forms of the general  equation were tested:

        Model Equation           Elasticity            Form Estimated

   Logarithmic

          N = KXa                    a                 InN = InK + alnX

   Linear

          N = K + aX              a &               N = K + aX

   Mixed Log-Linear

          N « KXaeBX              a + BX             InN = InK + alnX + BX

          N = K + alnX + BX        a + BX             N = K + alnX + BX
                                     N
where

     N = Dependent Variable,

     X = Independent Variable,

     K,a,B =  Parameters to be estimated.

Although a multi-mode model was  available, only the binary choice between
automobile and a general transit category was analyzed.   Similarly, the
number of purposes was reduced from  six to two, work and shopping, because
the study constraints were relatively strict.  As a great number of the
independent variables tested  exhibited substantial colinearity,  classical
regression (following appropriate log transformations) was unsuccessful in
providing the relationships  expected from economic theory.  To overcome
this difficulty, the least squares estimation of the coefficient was set
into a quadratic programming format,i.e., to find the set of coefficients
minimizing the sum of the squared residuals subject to a set of  constraints
on the said coefficients.  Through the use of such constraints on the
signs of the  coefficients, the model was fitted with elasticities compatible
with economic theory assumptions.  However,  because of high residual errors,
Kraft is very cautious about recommending the calibrated models  for planning
purposes.
                                 B-9

-------
The Economic Demand Model is a good example of a model, based on apparently
sound  theoretical foundations, which encountered serious, if not severe,
estimation problems.  The validity of the theoretical approach should not
be dismissed because of these problems, in view of the time and resources
constraints within which the urban application was performed in Boston.

ATTITUDINAL MODEL - WALLACE

In recent years, application of market research techniques has received
increased attention as a potential transportation planning tool.  Through
attitudinal surveys, a substantial amount of information has been gathered
concerning the perceived importance of modal attributes as well as the
travelers' level of relative satisfaction with these attributes.  Attitudinal
studies have been useful in identifying variables to be incorporated in
transportation models.  They have confirmed the importance of such variables
as travel time or cost used in most models.  In addition, they have pointed
out the great importance, from the user's standpoint, of such attributes as
reliability, convenience and comfort.  On the other hand, if modal split
models are to replicate users behavior, should they be founded on an
attitudinal base?  In other words, to what extent should behavior be inferred
from attitudes?  Economic studies have relied on the concept of revealed
preferences.  As far as modal split analysis is concerned, attitudinal
techniques should not be dismissed, at least at the present time inasmuch
as they offer two very interesting features.  First, they allow the use of
other  types of variables which cannot be quantified by "engineering" measures
such as pleasantness of the trip or privacy.  They offer a promise for
solving the new mode problem for which other models offer only partial
answers, if any.

An example of an attitudinal model based on market research techniques and
developed by Wallace (1968) at General Motors Laboratories is presented
hereafter.  Wallace's approach is predicated upon the requirement of defining
modes in terms of attributes which are mode independent.  The author identi-
fied three problems to be solved, namely;

        determination of a set of attributes which adequately describe
        a mode of transportation in the eyes of the travelers for a
        given trip purpose;

        specifications and calibration of a model to predict modal usage
        based on the above set of attributes; and

        if a new mode is to be considered, identification of procedures
        for estimating the attributes of a new mode of transportation as
        perceived by the traveler.

In the first problem, namely the determination of the set of attributes,
Wallace suggests that engineering measures can be understood by the consumer.
However, they do not provide an adequate description of the mode as perceived
                                 B-10

-------
 by the user.   These shortcomings  pertain very  often to  those qualitative
 attributes for which there is  no  single  quantitative measure that is both
 unambiguous and adequate to both  the  engineer  and the traveler.  Wallace
 offers the following list of potential variables:

         comfort,
      •  dependability of on-time  arrival,
      •  protection from weather while waiting,
         frequency of vehicle departure times,
         pleasantness of trip,
         attractiveness of vehicle,
      •  noise  (in vehicle),
         chance of accidents,
         exposure  to undesirable behavior of others,
      •  traffic,
         bodily crowding,
         out-of-pocket cost for trip,
         total  time spent riding,
         total  time spent walking,
         total  time spent waiting.

 The next question that arises  is  how  to  quantify these attributes.  Wallace
 proposes the use  of a technique often used in market research, -namely,
 Semantic Differential.   Briefly,  for  a given attribute a seven or eleven-
 point  rating scale is defined.  For example, if noise in the vehicle is
 the attribute  to  be rated,  the traveler  is asked to rate "very noisy" as
 0 and  "very quite" as 10.   To this end,  it might be expected that a traveler
 would  first determine his  perception  of  the noise level and then use 10, 0
 or an  intermediate rating  if the  noise level is respectively very high,
 like thunder,  or  inexistent.  However, what most travelers do after deter-
 mining their perception  of  the noise  level is to provide a rating which
 relates  their  satisfaction with that  level of the noise attribute to the
 satisfaction derived  from  the same attribute of some existing or ideal
 mode.

 To maintain an element of  consistency in the rating process, end points
 must be  used which will be most likely followed by the travelers.  To this
 end, the traveler  is  asked  to rate on a  scale which best describes his
 satisfaction or lack  thereof.  Thus,  to  "very noisy" is substituted
 "unsatisfactory"  or "poor" and to "very  quite" "completely acceptable"
 or "excellent."

Despite  a strong  tendency  to maintain attribute rating as value judgment
 free as  possible, Wallace maintains that better results are obtained when
 the notion of satisfaction is explicitly introduced, in which case ratings
are called Attribute  Satisfaction Ratings.  The next step of the analysis
 is the determination  of the relationship between the attribute satisfaction
ratings and attribute ratings.   Wallace admits that this is an area where
 considerable research is required.

The second major problem identified by Wallace is the specification and"
 calibration of a model.  Several  approaches have been used for predicting
demand for new products.  Wallace proposes a simple utility model in which


                                 B-ll

-------
 the utility of a given mode is defined as  being  equal  to  the sum of the
 utility or satisfaction derived from each  attribute.   Thus, the total
 utility IP- of mode i is expressed as

                                n        .
                         U1  =  S   U.(A  )
                               j=l   J  3

 where Uj is the satisfaction or utility obtained from  attribute A^ of mode i
 (j  - 1.....N).                                                   J

 It  is assumed that the relationship between Aj and Uj (A^) exhibits a
 diminishing return property, i.e.,  there is some maximum  level, U  ., of
 satisfaction attainable with the respect to the jth attribute and^alled
 the importance  of attribute j.   It  is  then Reasonable  to  assume that the
 relationship between the attribute  level A3- and its attribute satisfaction
 rating Qj(Al)  is linear,  i.e.,  U^ (A^)  = U- and 0 correspond respectively
 to  Qj (Aj )  i 10 and 0 (on an 11 point  scale) .  Thus , the  utility of mode i
 expressed in terms of the attribute satisfaction ratings  is given by:
                             .
It is  then  assumed  that product  (or mode) i will be preferred to k if
Focusing on  those individuals who prefer i to k  (denoted by | i) , the follow-
ing inequality  should hold for all individuals:

                      2  U  .  (Q i'i   n  kK
                      j   raj  0

A set of Umj can be found such that  the inequality holds for each individual
or individuals  in a given group.  Despite some problems (simplicity of a
linear model, different utility functions for different individuals) Wallace
claims that  the method is quite successful in predicting choice among alter-
native products.  Specifically, the model's accuracy has ranged from 70 to
95% with an  average of 85% in identifying an individual's first choice,
generally among 3 candidate products.  On this basis, Wallace believes that,
although never  used in transportation, the model would perform satisfactorily
in predicting the modal split of new modes.

The third and last problem mentioned by Wallace is the rating of the attri-
butes of a mode yet to be designed.  These ratings are required as inputs
to the model for modal split prediction.  Wallace believes that engineering
measures might  be helpful in evaluating the concept of a new mode.  He
also  believes  that the questionnaire technique can be useful to a limited
extent because  of the difficulty of communicating with printed matters.
He also feels that it would be premature, at this point of the planning of
                                  B-12

-------
 a new system,  to propose a demonstration program because of the often
 high costs of  such projects.

 Before designing a demonstration project, Wallace suggests, as an inter-
 mediate step,  to use a technique commonly used  in market research and
 called a product clinic.   The purpose of such an approach is to thoroughly
 familiarize a  sample of travlers with the new mode under study.  Travelers
 would be introduced to the new mode as realistically as possible by means
 of animated films,  vehicle mock-up, charts and  so forth, avoiding above
 all any "super sell" methods.  They would then  be asked to rate the modal
 attributes which would be used as inputs to the model.  Not only could
 such an approach provide  modal split estimates  for a new mode, but also
 it could prove to be very helpful in pointing out changes in systems design
 or operation which could  result in greater user acceptance, thus reducing
 the risk of failure of demonstration programs.

 In summary,  market research models have not been fully tested in transporta-
 tion planning  applications.  There is some doubt that future behavior can be
 accurately predicted based on existing attitudes elicited in a survey,
 especially if  the survey  is not carefully designed.  However, attitudinal
 surveys are helpful in identifying factors influencing modal split.  Atti-
 tudinal models such as those used in market research offer promise in
 taking account of non-quantifiable attributes,  treating the new mode
 problem,  and developing ridership estimates which can be valid for different
 geographic areas.

 SHOPPING TRIP  FREQUENCY MODEL - CHARLES RIVER ASSOCIATES, INC.

 This model compares  households which took one shopping trip in the 24-hour
 survey period  with  those  which took no shopping trip.  The hypothesis is
 that  the more  accessible  the household is to its relevant shopping areas}
 the more frequently  it will travel to them.  Alternatively, the more costly
 or  time consuming  it is to  make a shopping trip, the more carefully the
 household will plan  its shopping trips and the less frequently trips will
 be made.

 Although the model  is  limited to the choice between no trip and one trip
 per day,  it  can readily be  extended in a multiple choice framework to daily
 frequencies  greater  than  one.  The analysis in  this study was limited to
 zero and  one trip because only four households  in the sample had shopping
 trip frequencies  greater  than one.

 The sample for  this  model consists of 80 households, 26 of which recorded
 no shopping  trips and  59  of which recorded one trip in the survey period.
All the households are  drawn from the southern suburban corridor.  Again
 this was  done  to  enable alternate destinations  to be identified and
 correctly  located.   The sample is essentially the same one described
 earlier  for  the  choice  of destination model, with the households recording
more than  one  trip per  day  deleted, and a sample of zero trip households
 from the  same  areas  added.  The sample provides a good cross-section of
 downtown  and suburban  cross-town trips, but is  limited to auto travel and
                                  B-13

-------
 is further limited  in  terms of  socioeconoraic variety.

 Before undertaking  this analysis it is necessary to construct the potential
 shopping trips  for  the zero-trip households.  That is, if the household were
 to take a shopping  trip, where  would it go, by what mode, and at what time
 of day?  This is  done  in a straightforward way, employing the results of
 the previous stages of analysis.

 First, the relevant destinations are selected by use of the matrix of
 shopping destinations  developed earlier to analyze choice of destination.
 Then the times  and  costs of travel to each destination are generated from
 the network information.  Finally inclusive prices of travel to each
 destination are computed from the parameters estimated in the modal choice
 model.   In this study, the inclusive prices of travel for the zero trip
 households were based  only on the times and costs of auto trips, because
 the sample of zero  trip households was drawn from a suburban area where all
 the observed shopping  trips were made by auto.  But as described earlier,
 this could be generalized by constructing a weighted average of the
 inclusive  price of  travel for each mode to a given destination, using as
 weights  the computed probabilities from the modal choice function.

 To  generalize further, the inclusive price could also be averaged over times
 of  day of  travel, using as weights the computed probabilities of time of
 day of  travel from  the time of day model.  However, given the quality of
 the alternate time  of day data or suburban auto trips, there seemed little
 point  in applying this refinement for this analysis.

 The final  preparatory step before attempting to model the effect of the
 cost or  disutility  of travel on trip frequency, is to develop an overall
 price  of travel for each household.  Each household has a number of
 alternative destinations, for each of which there is an inclusive price
 of  travel.  The natural measure of the overall price of travel to shop for
 each household  is some weighted average of the inclusive prices of travel
 to  each  of  the household's alternative destinations.  The obvious weights
 to  use are  the  computed probabilities from the choice of destination model.
 Thus, we define the overall price of shopping for houshold t as
                             d
where ht(d) is the estimated probability of household t selecting its dth
destination and pt(d) is tne inclusive price of travel for household t to
its dth destination.  This overall price was computed for both the zero
trip households and the one trip households in the sample, using an
earlier equation.

Similarly, a weighted average of the shopping opportunities at each destina
tion was developed by weighting the zonal employment figure by the computed
probabilities from the choice of destination mode.  Thus, we define

                                         s'd>
                                 B-14

-------
 where ht(d)  is  as defined above and Et(d) is the percentage of the region's
 retail trade employment found in observation t's destination zone d.   The
 two variables ft and ^t provide measures of the cost of travel to shop for
 household  t  and the shopping opportunities which the traveler t receives
 if he takes  a trip.

 The trip frequency models were estimated using the binary choice logit
 model.  The  best results were as follows:

                 log  Q =  -1.72(p-o)  + 3.90(E-o)
                            (3.16)         (3.61)

 where Qt   =  the odds that household t will make a daily shopping trip.
                                                                     /s
      -o)   =  the comparison between taking a trip and incurring price  p
             and not taking a trip and incurring zerio cost of travel.

   (Et-o)   -  the comparison between taking a trip and obtaining proximity
             to £ shopping facilities or opportunities,  and not taking a
             trip and obtaining proximity to zero facilities.

 Both the price  and employment variables in the above equation have the cor-
 rect  sign and  are highly significant.  The model states that for shopping
 the  frequency of travel is significant inversely related to the time and
 cost of travel.  If travel times are reduced through improvements in the
 transportation  system the frequency of shopping should increase.  The
 model can be used to predict the expected increase in the number of shop-
 ping trips induced by the change in the transportation system.

A number of alternative models were estimated to test the significance of
 each  of the available socioeconomic variables (including car ownership)
 and weather variables.   None of them was significant.   Interestingly,  the
 only  such variable which resulted in a t-statistic greater than 1.0 was
 family income,  and this was the only choice model for which income was
 even  remotely significant.  The equation is as follows:

                log Q  =   -2,25p +  2.8SE -  .199!
                   9       (3.30)     (2.39)    (1.02)

The results suggest that wealthier families shop less frequently,  which
seems plausible since  they are more likely to have necessary facilities
to carry larger stocks  of goods.

The predictive record  of the trip frequency model is reasonably good;
60 of the 80 observations were correctly predicted.
                                    B-15

-------
               ECONOMETRIC MODEL OF GASOLINE CONSUMPTION
               	DATA RESOURCES, INC.

An econometric analysis of the demand for gasoline is made with four
different data sets, each of which measures a slightly different version
of the aggregate sales of gasoline.  The following listing indicates
that the short term price elasticity (which measures the percentage
decrease in consumption with respect to a one percent change in price)
of demand for gasoline is .12 for the broadest aggregate of gasoline sales
and .16 for the narrowest definition of gasoline consumption (short term
is defined as three months).  The short term income elasticity (defined
as the percentage increase in consumption with respect to a one percent
change in income) is approximately.27 with estimates running as low as .23
and as high as .32.  The long term income and price elasticities (which
require roughly ten quarters to be fully achieved) are 1.01 and .48.  They
range from .42 to .54 for price and .94 to 1.08 for income.
                                  B-16

-------
                    RESULTS  USING THE ERROR  COMPONENT
                        ESTIMATION  TECHNIQUE WITH
                        A LINEAR QUARTERLY  MODEL
                            FOR ALL STATES
Data Source
API Gasoline

SRE
LRE
API Motor Gasoline

SRE
LRE
FHA Motor Fuel

SRE
LRE
FHA Highway Motor
Fuel less Highway
Special Fuels
SRE
LRE
Price
-487.2
(66.1)
-.121
-.417
-467.7
(62.7)
-.120
-.441
-495.9
(64.7)
-.114
-.527
-581.5
(61.7)
-.160
-.540
Income
13658.
(828.)
.275
.944
13288.
(829.)
.276
1.014
12605.
(844.)
.234
1.084
14308.
(813.)
.318
1.062
Lagged
Consumption
.709
(.016)


.727
(.016)


.783
(.014)


.700
(.016)


Standard errors in parentheses
SRE represents short run elasticities
LRE represents long run elasticities
Estimation period is from 63:2 to 72:4
                                                                      R  on
                                                                   Transformed
                                                                      Data

                                                                       .89
                                                                       ,91
                                                                       .93
                                                                       .91
                                  B-17

-------
        APPENDIX C

STATISTICAL TRANSPORTATION
     ANALYSIS TABLES

-------
BA.SE CONDITION




ANALYSIS TABLES
      C-l

-------
                                                TRAVEL TIME - WORK
  0
  1
  2
  3
  4
  5

Total
         Income of $0,000-4,999
         Automobile    Transit
           Person     Passenger
                         Income of $5.000-9.999
 8,688
 3,718
 2,269
 2,452
 5,150
	0

 22,275
 2,041
   552
   413
   244
    88
	0

 3.338
Automobile
Person
49,667
38,982
21,429
35,732
45,199
3
191,012
Transit
Passenger
7,062
3,247
2,322
2,172
352
0
15,156
                                     Income of $10,000 and Over
                                      Automobile    Transit
                                        Person     Passenger
                                 Total For
                             All Income Groups
 53,020
 69,429
 24,317
 55,485
 51,880
	2

254.133
  5,473
  4,655
  1,996
  2,714
    232
	0

 15,069
Automobile
  Person

 111,373
 112,130
  48,014
  93,669
 102,229
 	5

 467.421
 Transit
Passenger

  14,575
   8,455
   4,730
   5,131
     671
 	0

  33,562
                                                TRAVEL TIME - OTHER
  0
  1
  2
  3
  4
  5

Total
         Income of $0.000-4,999
         Automobile     Transit
           Person     Passenger
                          Income of  $5,000-9,999
 20,197
  8,133
  3,354
  4,478
  7,915
	7

 44,082
 5,099
   673
   732
   263
   170
	0

 6.937
Automobile
Person
90,334
66,714
29,878
52,344
57,281
85
296,637
Transit
Passenger
9,589
2,032
3,035
1,193
492
0
16,342
                                     Income  of  $10,000 and Over
                                      Automobile    Transit
                                         Person    Passenger
                                 Total For
                             All Income Groups
 82,556
105,553
 32,405
 75,869
 65,483
	56_

361,921
  4,893
  2,323
  2,198
  1,305
    235
	0

 10,955
Automobile
  Person

 193,086
 180,400
  65,637
 132,690
 130,679
     147

 702,639
 Transit
Passenger

  19,582
   5,028
   5,966
   2,762
     867
 	0

  34,233

-------
                                                       TRAVEL TIME - TOTAL
                                                                                                        Total For
o
CO
Income of $0,000-4,999


0
1
2
3
4
5
Automobile
Person
28,885
11,851
5,623
6,930
13,065
7
Transit
Passenger
7,140
1,225
1,145
507
258
0
Income of $5,000-9,999
Automobile
Person
140,001
105,696
51,307
88,076
102,480
88
Transit
Passenger
16,651
5,279
'5,357
3,365
844
0
Income of $10,000 and Over
Automobile
Person
135,576
174,982
56,722
131,354
17,363
58
Transit
Passenger
10,366
6,978
4,194
4,019
467
0
All Income Groups
Automobile
Person
304,459
292,530
113,651
226,359
232,908
152
Transit
Passenger
34,157
13,483
10,696
7,893
1,538
0
      Total
66,357
10,275
487,649
31,498
616,054
26.024
1,170.060
67,795

-------
                                                TRAVEL COST - WORK
         Income of $0,000-4,999
  0
  1
  2
  3
  4
  5

Total
Automobile
Person
124
55
34
34
81
0
328
Transit
Passenger
6
1
1
1
0
0
9
                      Income of $5,000-9,999   Income of $10,000 and Over
Automobile
Person
706
582
319
512
723
0
2,843
Transit
Passenger
19
8
6
4
1
0
39
Automobile
Person
748
1,042
361
803
827
0
3,781
Transit
Passenger
14
12
5
5
1
0
38
                                                                    Total For
                                                                All Income Groups
Automobile
Person
1,579
1,679
714
1,348
1,631
0
6,952
Transit
Passenger
39
21
12
10
2
0
84
                                                TRAVEL COST - OTHER
  0
  1
  2
  3
  4
  5

Total
         Income of $0,000-4,999
         Automobile    Transit
           Person     Passenger
 224
 100
  38
  49
  95
	0

 505
18
 1
 2
 1
 1
 0

23
                       Income of  $5,000-9.999
                       Automobile   Transit
                        Person     Passenger
                                 Income of $10,000 and Over
   990
   799
   336
   591
   691
	1

 3,409
35
 4
11
 2
 3
 0

55
Automobile
Person
895
1,266
365
861
799
1
4,187
Transit
Passenger
17
4
8
2
1
0
32
                                                          Total For
                                                      All Income Groups
Automobile
  Person

   2,110
   2,166
     739
   1,499
   1,587
  	2

   8,103
 Transit
Passenger

      69
       9
      22
       5
       5
  	0

     110

-------
                                                       TRAVEL COST - TOTAL
                                                                                                        Total For
o
0
1
2
3
4
5
Income of $0,000-4,999
Automobile
Person
348
155
72
83
176
0
Transit
Passenger
24
2
3
1
1
0
Income of $5,000-9,999
Automobile
Person
1,696
1,381
655
1,103
1,414
1
Transit
Passenger
54
12
17
6
4
0
Income of $10,000 and Over
Automobile
Person
1,643
2,308
726
1,664
1,626
1
Transit
Passenger
31
16
13
7
2
0
All Income Groups
Automobile
Person
3,689
3,845
1,453
2,847
3,218
2
Transit
Passenger
108
30
34
15
7
0
       Total
            833
31
6,252
93
7,968
69
15,055
194

-------
                                                     PERSON TRIPS - TOTAL
  MSA

    0
    1
    2
    3
    4
    5

  Total

Automobile
Person
139,974
51,834
24,932
27,933
50,646
12
295,331
Income of
Automobile
Driver
101,878
37,809
18,467
20,481
37,461
8
216,104
$0,000-4,999
Automobile
Passenger
40,181
14,769
6,731
7,816
13,742
4
83,243
Income of $5,000-9,999
Transit
Passenger
15,628
1,961
2,382
711
883
0
21,564
Automobile
Person
660,589
436,437
216,724
336,578
370,509
162
2,020,999
Automobile
Driver
486,307
322,247
161,174
250,218
275,982
113
1,496,040
Automobile
Passenger
182,292
119,166
57,639
76,733
97,951
54
546,734
Transit
Passenger
34,706
8,273
11,576
4,580
2,846
0
61,980
o
I
                             Income of $10,000 and Over
   MSA

    0
    1
    2
    3
    4
    5

  Total
Automobile
Person
623,224
710,968
232,972
501,681
416,194
106
2,485,142
Automobile
Driver
462,430
528,776
173,787
374,525
310,863
73
1,850,453
Automobile
Passenger
167,147
189,030
61,255
131,514
108,896
35
657,876
Transit
Passenger
19,761
10,620
8,945
5,323
1,427
0
46,076
              Total For All Income Groups
Automobile
Person
1,423,787
1,199,239
474,628
866,191
837,349
281
Automobile
Driver
1,050,615
888,831
353,428
645,226
624,305
195
Automobile
Passenger
389,620
322,966
125,623
228,961
220,588
93
Transit
Passenger
70,094
20,854
22,903
10,614
5,156
0
4,801,472
3,562,596
1,287.852
129,620

-------
                                             PERSON TRIPS FOR NON-WORK PURPOSE
 MSA

  0
  1
  2
  3
  4
  5

Total
Income of $0,000-4,999
Automobile
Person
99,950
36,442
15,589
18,892
32,026
11
202,912
Automobile
Driver
66,192
24,134
10,324
12,511
21,209
7
134,379
Automobile
Passenger
33,758
12,308
5,265
6,381
10,817
4
68,533
Transit
Passenger
11,923
1,042
1,630
363
632
0
15,591
Automobile
Person
433,584
279,863
130,990
204,047
220,893
154
1,269,530
Income of $5,000-9,999
Automobile
Driver
287,142
185,340
86,748
135,130
146,287
102
840,748
Automobile
Passenger
146,442
94,523
44,242
68,917
74,606
52
428,782
Transit
Passenger
22,493
2,978
7,349
1,557
1,922
0
36,298
                         Income of  $10,000 and Over
 MSA

  0
  1
  2
  3
  4
  5

Total
Automobile
Person
383,952
429,434
137,149
293,301
242,242
100
i
1,486,176
Automobile
Driver
254,273
284,393
90,827
194,239
160,425
66

984,222
Automobile
Passenger
129,679
145,041
46,322
99,062
81,817
34

501,954
Transit
Passenger
10,718
3,202
5,309
1,650
866
0

21,745
              Total For All Income Groups
 Automobile
   Person

  917,486
  745,739
  283,727
  516,240
  495,160
      267

2,958,617
Automobile
  Driver

  607,607
  493,867
  187,899
  341,881
  327,921
      177

1.959,349
Automobile
Passenger

 309,879
 251,872
  95,828
 174,359
 167,239
 	90

 999,268
 Transit
Passenger

  45,133
   7,222
  14,288
   3,571
   3,420
 	0

  73,634

-------
                                                   PERSON TRIPS FOR WORK
 MSA

  0
  1
  2
  3
  4
  5

Total
Income of $0,000-4,999
Automobile
Person
42,109
16,136
9,609
9,405
19,177
1
96,435
Automobile
Driver
35,686
13,675
8,143
7,970
16,252
1
81,725
Automobile
Passenger
6,423
2,461
1,466
1,435
2,925
0
14,710
Transit
Passenger
3,974
930
783
352
265
0
6,304
Automobile
Person
235,015
161,550
87,823
135,804
153,040
13
773,244
Income of $5,000-9,999
Automobile
Driver
199,165
136,907
74,426
115,088
129,695
11
655,292
Automobile
Passenger
35,850
24,643
13,397
20,716
23,345
2
117,952
Transit
Passenger
12,620
5,278
4,355
3,010
961
0
26,224
                        Income of $10,000 and Over
                                                        Total For All  Income Groups
 MSA

  0
  1
  2
  3
  4
  5
Automobile
Person
245,625
288,372
97,893
212,738
177,517
8
Automobile
Driver
208,157
244,383
82,960
180,286
150,438
7
Automobile
Passenger
37,468
43,989
14,933
32,452
27,079
1
Transit
Passenger
9,174
7,367
3,718
3,649
575
0
Automobile
Person
522,749
466,058
195,324
357,947
349,733
21
Automobile
Driver
443,008
394,964
165,529
303,345
296,384
18
Automobile
Passenger
79,141
71,094
29,795
54,602
53,349
3
Transit
Passenger
25,768
13,574
8,856
7,009
1,801
0
Total   1.022,153
866,231
155.922
24,482
1,891.831
1,603.247
288.584
57.010

-------
                                                     PERSON MILES - OTHER
o
i
vo
            0
            1
            2
            3
            4
            5

          Total
            0
            1
            2
            3
            4
            5
Income of $0,000-4
Automobile
Driver
342,481
151,927
64,428
82,957
166,075
157
808,027
Income
Automobile
Driver
1,417,537
2,052,127
618,802
1,452,696
1,392,669
1,382
Automobile
Passenger
174,665
77,482
32,858
42,308
84,699
81
412,093
of $10,000 and
Automobile
Passenger
722,944
1,046,585
315,590
740,875
710,261
705
,999
Transit
Passenger
31,202
6,178
6,267
2,601
6,071
0
46,855
Over
Transit
Passenger
30,604
20,754
16,287
13,244
868
0
Income
Automobile
Driver
1,543,592
1,281,096
571,893
998,918
1,205,104
2,114
5,602,716
of $5,000-9,
Automobile
Passenger
787,231
653,358
291,666
509,449
614,603
1,078
2,857,385
Total For All Income
Automobile
Driver
3,303,610
3,485,149
1,255,123
2,534,572
2,763,847
3,655
Automobile
Passenger
1,684,840
1,777,426
640,112
1,292,632
1,409,562
1,864
999
Transit
Passenger
57,145
18,586
23,670
12,343
1,780
0
113,523
Groups
Transit.
Passenger
118,950
45,517
46,225
28,188
3,256
0
          Total
6,935,211
3,536,959
81,757
13,345,952
6.806.436
242,136

-------
                                                     PERSON MILES - WORK
o
i
           0
           1
           2
           3
           4
           5

         Total
           0
           1
           2
           3
           4
           5

Automobile
Driver
186,698
88,777
57,481
56,862
140,799
6
530,620
Income of $0,000-4
Automobile
Passenger
33,605
15,979
10,347
10,235
25,343
1
95,511
Income of $10,000 and
Automobile
Driver
1,154,450
1,691,219
603,422
1,339,878
1,441,801
51
Automobile
Passenger
207,801
304,420
108,616
241,178
259,524
9
,999
Transit
Passenger
10,492
3,817
3,439
1,829
320
0
19,896
Over
Transit
Passenger
30,098
31,785
14,848
21,573
977
0
Income of $5,000-9,
Automobile
Driver
1,078,034
948,071
535,679
857,116
1,260,114
79
4,679,092
Total
Automobile
Driver
2,419,182
2,728,065
1,196,582
2,253,856
2,842,712
135
Automobile
Passenger
194,096
170,6521
96,423
154,281
226,821
14
842,236
For All Income
Automobile
Passenger
435,452
491,052
215,384
405,694
511,688
24
999
Transit
Passenger
37,657
22,509
18,433
17,131
1,457
0
97,187
Groups
Transit
Passenger
78,248
58,111
36,720
40,532
2,755
0
         Total
6,230,820
1,121,548
99.283
11,440.531
2,059,295
216,366

-------
                                           PERSON MILES - TOTAL
  0
  1
  2
  3
  4
  5

Total
  0
  1
  2
  3
  4
  5

Automobile
Driver
529,179
240,704
121,909
139,819
306,874
163
1,338,647
Income of $0,000-4
Automobile
Passenger
208,270
93,461
43,205
52,543
110,042
82
507,604
Income of $10,000 and
Automobile
Driver
2,571,987
3,743,346
1,222,224
2,792,574
2,834,470
1,433
Automobile
Passenger
930,745
1,351,005
454,206
982,053
969,785
714
,999
Transit
Passenger
41,694
9,995
9,706
4,430
927
0
66,752
Over
Transit
Passenger
60,702
52,539
31,135
34,817
1,845
0
Income of $5,000-9,
Automobile
Driver
2,621,626
2,229,167
1,107,572
1,856,034
2,465,218
2,193
10,281,808
Total
Automobile
Driver
5,722,792
6,213,214
2,451,705
4,788,428
5,606,559
3,790
Automobile
Passenger
981,327
824,010
388,089
663,730
841,424
1,092
3,699,621
For All Income
Automobile
Passenger
2,120,292
2,268,478
855,496
1,698,326
1,921,250
1,888
999
Transit
Passenger
94,802
41,095
42,103
29,474
3,237
0
210,710
Groups
Transit
Passenger
197,198
103,628
82,945
68,720
6,011
0
Total
13,166,031
4,658,507
181,040
24,786,483
8.865,731
458,502

-------
EPA PROMULGATED PIAN




   ANALYSIS TABLES
        C-12

-------
                                                      PERSON TRIPS - TOTAL
    0
    1
    2
    3
    4
    5

   Total
o
>-*
LO
    0
    1
    2
    3
    4
    5

   Total
Income of $0,000-4,999
Automobile
Person
128,301
47,426
22,902
25,651
46,141
11
271,545
•
Automobile
Person
570,026
659,150
214,286
267,080
391,763
101
T
2,302,403
Automobile
Driver
76,197
27,968
13,123
14,949
26,249
7
159,231
Income of $10,
Automobile
Driver
389,671
451,022
146,803
320,113
268,646
68
1,576,319
Automobile
Passenger
52,104
19,458
9,778
10,702
19,892
3
112,314
000 and Over
Automobile
Passenger
180,355
208,128
67,483
136,967
123,117
33
726,084
Transit
Passenger
16,620
2,834
2,832
1,145
1,065
0
24,496

Transit
Passenger
32,255
21,733
14,313
11,644
2,261
0
82,208
Automobile
Person
599,567
402,696
197,863
312,184
346,988
155
1,859,453

Automobile
Person
1,297,893
1,109,272
435,051
804,914
786,008
266
4,433,401
Income of $5,000-9,999
Automobile
Driver
380,735
255,215
124,849
197,008
218,542
102
1,176,438
Total For All
Automobile
Driver
846,589
734,205
284,776
532,070
514,176
177
2,911,989
Automobile
Passenger
218,832
147,481
73,014
115,176
128,446
53
683,015
Income Groups
Automobile
Passenger
451,304
375,067
150,275
272,844
271,832
89
1,521,412
Transit
Passenger
50,071
15,464
17,733
9,361
4,351
0
96,979

Transit
Passenger
98,946
40,031
34,879
22,149
7,678
0
203,682

-------
o
I
                                                      PERSON TRIPS  - OTHER
    0
    1
    2
    3
    4
    5

   Total
Income of $0,000-4,999
Automobile
Person
89,744
32,302
13,924
16,689
27,199
10
180,983
Automobile
Driver
59,433
21,392
9,221
11,052
18,013
7
119,856
Automobile
Passenger
30,311
10,910
4,703
5,637
9,186
3
61,127
Transit
Passenger
9,094
892
1,418
350
565
0
12,319
Automobile
Person
378,779
247,709
114,289
180,641
194,981
142
1,116,541
Income of
Automobile
Driver
250,860
164,046
75,688
119,630
129,126
94
739,431
$5,000-9,999
Automobile
Passenger
127,919
83,663
38,601
61,011
65,855
48
377,110

Transit
Passenger
23,224
3,623
9,129
2,090
2,357
0
40,423
                         Income of $10,000 and Over
                                                       Total For All Income Groups
    0
    1
    2
    3
    4
    5
Automobile
Person
336,136
380,507
120,289
259,746
214,94,9
93
Automobile
Driver
222,607
251,991
79,662
172,017
142,350
62
Automobile
Passenger
113,529
128,516
40,627
77,729
72,599
31
Transit
Passenger
11,346
4,637
6,699
2,591
983
0
Automobile
Person
804,658
660,518
248,502
457,075
438,245
244
Automobile
Driver
532,886
437,429
164,571
302,699
290,228
162
Automobile
Pas_senger_
271,772
223,089
83,931
154,376
148,017
82
Transit
Passenger
43,664
9,153
17,247
5,031
3,905
0
   Total  1,311,718
868.687
443,031
26,258
2.609,242
1,727,975
881.267
78,999

-------
o
I
                                                      PERSON TRIPS - WORK
    0
    1
    2
    3
    4
    5

   Total
Income of $0,000-4,999
Automobile
Person
38,557
15,124
8,978
8,962
18,942
1
90,562
Automobile
Driver
16,764
6,576
3,903
3,897
8,236
1
39,375
Automobile
Passenger
21,793
8,548
5,075
5,065
10,706
0
51,187
Transit
Passenger
7,526
1,942
1,414
795
500
0
12,177
Automobile
Person
220,788
154,987
83,574
131,543
152,007
13
742,912
Income of
Automobile
Driver
129,875
91,169
49,161
77,378
89,416
8
437,007
$5,000-9,999
Automobile
Passenger
90,913
63,818
34,413
54,165
62,591
5
305,905

Transit
Passenger
26,847
11,841
8,604
7,271
1,994
0
56,556
                         Income of $10,000 and Over
    0
    1
    2
    3
    4
    5
Automobile
Person
233,890
278,643
93,997
207,334
176,814
8
Automobile
Driver
167,064
199,031
67,141
148,096
126,296
6
Automobile
Passenger
66,826
79,612
26,856
59,238
50,518
2
Transit
Passenger
20,909
17,096
7,614
9,053
1,278
0
                                                        Total For All  Income Groups
Automobile
Person
493,235
448,754
186,549
347,839
347,763
22
Automobile
Driver
313,703
296,776
120,205
229,371
223,948
15
Automobile
Passenger
179,532
151,978
66,344
118,468
123,815
7
Transit
Passenger
55,282
30,878
17,632
17,118
3,773
0
   Total    990,685
707,632
283,053
55,950
1.824,159
1.184.014
640,145
124.683

-------
o
I
                                                    PERSON MILES - TOTAL
          0
          1
          2
          3
          4
          5

        Total
Income of $0,000-4,999
Automobile
Driver
427,988
129,531
92,434
110,273
238,298
159
1,060,700
Automobile
Passenger
305,033
138,871
72,832
82,408
180,665
84
783,927
Transit
Passenger
37,764
11,333
11,527
5,462
1,290
0
67,377
Income of $5,000-9,999
Automobile
Driver
2,223,526
1,899,847
924,489
1,577,568
2,087,732
2,132
8,703,895
Automobile
Passenger
1,291,117
1,105,213
547,597
928,173
1,245,333
1,099
5,110,544
Transit
Passenger
128,089
63,924
63,712
48,039
5,679
0
309,412
                            Income of $10,000 and Over
          0
          1
          2
          3
          4
          5
Automobile
Driver
2,310,966
3,402,363
1,099,296
2,543,425
2,605,590
1,397
Automobile
Passenger
1,065,445
1,569,100
502,244
1,155,406
1,186,911
708
Transit
Passenger
94,157
92,462
49,225
61,535
3,429
0
                                                                 Total For  All  Income Groups
Automobile
Driver
4,962,465
5,494,741
2,116,351
4,231,265
4,932,359
3,687
Automobile
Passenger
2,661,607
2,813,183
1,122,741
2,175,986
2,613,285
1,891
Transit
Passenger
259,980
167,719
124,463
115,034
10,398
0
        Total
11,951,148
5,485.058
300,807
21,715.743
11.379,527
677,596

-------
                                                     PERSON MILES - OTHER
o
i
            0
            1
            2
            3
            4
            5

          Total
Income of $0,000-4,999
Automobile
Driver
318,168
141,037
59,914
77,149
155,851
154
753,143
Automobile
Passenger
162,266
71,429
30,556
39,346
79,484
78
384,104
Transit
Passenger
17,503
4,001
5,389
1,869
611
0
29,374
                                                                                       Income of $5.000-9,999
Automobile
Driver
1,396,480
1,182,531
523,924
926,972
1,137,420
2,069
Automobile
Passenger
712,185
603,091
267,201
472,755
580,085
1,055
Transit
Passenger
50,766
17,874
28,456
12,794
2,400
0
 5,169,382
2,636,385
112,289
                              Income of $10,000 and Over
            Total For All Income Groups
            0
            1
            2
            3
            4
            5

          Total
Automobile
Driver
1,282,351
1,892,317
568,415
1,345,775
1,315,226
1,353
6,405,435
Automobile
Passenger
653,999
965,082
289,891
676,346
670,766
690
3,266,773
Transit
Passenger
30,154
25,102
19,873
16,304
1,137
0
92,569
  Automobile
    Driver

 2,996,984
 3,215,885
 1,152,385
 2,349,895
 2,609,236
     3,575

12,327,960
 Automobile
 Passenger

1,528,462
1,640,101
  587,716
1,198,446
1,330,711
    1,823

6,287.260
 Transit
Passenger

 98,423
 46,977
 53,717
 30,965
  4,148
	0

234,232

-------
                                                     PERSON MILES - WORK
o
i
CO
           0
           1
           2
           3
           4
           5

         Total

Automobile
Driver
109,820
51,494
32,520
33,124
82,447
5
307,557
Income of $0,000-
Automobile
Passenger
142,767
66,942
42,276
43,062
101,181
6
399,823
-4,999
Transit
Passenger
20,261
7,332
6,138
3,593
679
0
38 , 003

Automobile
Driver
827,046
717,316
400,565
650,596
950,312
63
3,534,513
Income of $5,000-9,999
Automobile
Passenger
578,932
502,122
280,396
455,418
665,248
44
2,474,159

Transit
Passenger
77,293
46,050
35,256
35,245
3,279
0
197,123
                             Income of $10,000 and Over
           0
           1
           2
           3
           4
           5
Automobile
Driver
1,028,615
1,510,046
530,881
1,147,650
1,290,364
44
Automobile
Passenger
411,446
604,018
212,353
479,060
516,145
18
Transit
Passenger
64,003
67,360
29,352
45,231
2,292
0
                                                               Total For All Income Groups
                                                     Automobile
                                                       Driver

                                                     1,965,481
                                                     2,278,856
                                                       963,966
                                                     1,881,370
                                                     2,323,123
                                                           112
                                                     Automobile
                                                     Passenger

                                                    1,133,145
                                                    1,173,082
                                                      535,025
                                                      977,540
                                                    1,282,574
                                                           68
                                                    Transit
                                                   Passenger

                                                   161,557
                                                   120,742
                                                    70,746
                                                    84,069
                                                     6,250
                                                         0
         Total
5.545.713
2,218.285
208.238
9.387,783
5,092.267
443,364

-------
                                                    TRAVEL TIME - WORK
      0
      1'
      2
      3
      4
      5

    Total
             Income of $0.000-4,999
             Automobile    Transit
               Person     Passenger
                          Income  of  $5,000-9,999    Income  of  $10,000 and Over
 10,811
  4,543
  2,697
  2,961
  6,448
	0

 27,205
 4,077
 1,150
   776
   532
   192
	0

 6,727
Automobile
Person
56,676
44,435
23,961
40,344
51,181
4
220,422
Transit
Passenger
15,205
7,173
4,686
4,931
813
0
32,808
Automobile
Person
58,683
75,484
26,404
60,313
56,740
2
278,283
Transit
Passenger
12,317
10,583
4,155
6,263
560
0
33,878
                                                                        Total For
                                                                    All Income Groups
Automobile
Person
126,170
124,462
53,062
103,618
114,369
6
525,910
Transit
Passenger
31,598
18,906
9,617
11,726
1,565
0
73,412
o
I
                                                    TRAVEL TIME - OTHER
      0
      1
      2
      3
      4
      5

    Total
             Income of $0,000-4,999
             Automobile    Transit
               Person     Passenger
                          Income  of $5,000-9,999   Income  of  $10,000 and Over
 18,593
 '7,453
  3,087
  4,101
  7,321
	7

 40.562
 3,587
   524
   663
   229
   179
	0

 5,183
Automobile
Person
80,657
60,818
26,976
47,916
52,996
83
269,445
Transit
Passenger
9,835
2,273
3,849
1,434
685
0
18,077
Automobile
Person
73,791
96,210
29,357
69,375
60,730
54
329,518
Transit
Passenger
5,347
3,164
2,869
1,829
314
0
13,522
                                                                        Total For
                                                                    All Income Groups
Automobile
  Person

 173,041
 164,481
  59,421
 121,393
 121,047
     143

 639,524
 Transit
Passenger

  18,769
   5,962
   7,381
   3,492
   1,177
 	0

  36,782

-------
                                                TRAVEL TIME - TOTAL
                                                                                                 Total For
Income of $0,000-4,999



o
i
ro
o





0
1
2
3
4
5
Automobile
Person
29,404
11,996
5,784
7,062
13,769
7
Transit
Passenger
7,664
1,674
1,439
761
371
0
Income of $5,000-9,999
Automobile
Person
137,333
105,253
50,937
88,260
104,177
87
Transit
Passenger
25,040
9,446
8,535
6,365
1,498
0
Income of $10,000 and Over
Automobile
Person
132,474
171,694
55,761
129,688
117,470
56
Transit
Passenger
17,664
13,747
7,024
8,092
874
0
All Income Groups
Automobile
Person
299,211
288,943
112,483
225,011
235,416
149
Transit
Passenger
50,367
24,868
16,998
15,218
2,742
0
Total
67,767
11.910
489.867
50.885
607.801
47.400
1,165.434
110.194

-------
                                                    TRAVEL COST - WORK
             Income of $0,000-4,999
      0
      1
      2
      3
      4
      5

    Total
Automobile
Person
188
77
47
47
104
0
461
Transit
Passenger
12
3
2
1
1
0
19
                        Income of $5,000-9,999   Income of $10,000 and Over
Automobile
Person
1,465
1,092
590
942
1,185
0
5,268
Transit
Passenger
41
18
13
11
3
0
87
Automoible
Person
1,890
2,386
809
1,802
1,667
0
8,548
Transit
Passenger
32
26
12
14
2
0
86
                                                                    Total For
                                                                All Income Groups
Automobile
Person
3,543
3,555
1,446
2,791
2,956
0
14,277
Transit
Passenger
85
48
27
26
6
0
192
I
NJ
                                                    TRAVEL COST - OTHER
      0
      1
      2
      3
      4
      5

    Total
             Income of $0,000-4,999
             Automobile    Transit
               Person     Passenger
 ,  666
   257
   106
   131
   234
	0

 1,394
15
 1
 2
 0
 1
 0

19
                         Income of $5.000-9,999   Income of $10,000 and Over
Automobile
Person
2,824
2,000
890
1,468
1,647
2
8,832
Transit
Passenger
36
6
15
3
3
0
63
Automobile
Person
2,523
3,107
949
2,122
1,851
1
10,552
Transit
Passenger
18
7
10
4
1
0
40
                                                                    Total For
                                                                All Income Groups
Automobile
Person
6,013
5,364
1,945
3,721
3,732
3
20,778
Transit
Passenger
69
14
27
7
5
0
122

-------
                                                     TRAVEL COST - TOTAL
                                                                                                      Total For
o
to
to
0
1
2
3
4
5
Income of $0,000-4,999
Automobile
Person
854
334
153
178
338
0
Transit
Passenger
27
4
4
1
2
0
Income of $5,000-9,999
Automobile
Person
4,289
3,092
1,480
2,410
2,832
2
Transit
Passenger
77
24
28
14
6
0
Income of $10,000 and Over
Automobile
Person
4,413
5,493
1,758
3,924
3,518
1
Transit
Passenger
50
33
22
18
3
0
All Income Groups
Automobile
Person
9,556
8,919
3,391
6,512
6,688
3
Transit
Passenger
154
61
54
33
11
0
     Total
          1,855
38
14,100
150
19.100
126
35.055
314

-------