RECYCLING
 Reprinted from
 GOVERNMENT
 AND THE NATION'S RESOURCES:
 REPORT
 OF THE NA TIONAL COMMISSION
 ON SUPPLIES
AND SHORTAGES, December 1976



-------
     2d  Printing,  October  1977
    An environmental protection publication
  in the solid waste management series (SW-601)
U.S. ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY

                  1977

-------
                               FOREWORD

   The National Commission on Supplies and Shortages, established by Public Law
93-426, is the latest major attempt by our nation to obtain advice on how best to
use our natural resources.  The Commission's final report, Government and the
Nation's Resources,  was published  in  December  1976  and was distributed in
limited  quantities.  Chapter  8 of the report, "Recycling," contains material of
particular relevance to those  concerned with conservation issues. The Environ-
mental Protection Agency has played a significant role in promoting recycling, and
this role will be expanded under the Resource Conservation and Recovery Act of
1976. To ensure that the Commission's findings and recommendations on recycling
reach a wide audience, EPA decided to reprint and distribute copies of the chapter.
   The major findings and recommendations of Chapter 8 are as follows:

   •  Recycling can reduce the escalating capital requirements and environmental
degradation which accompany the exploitation of lower grade virgin  resources;
national energy demands; and dependence on imports.
   •  Sizable amounts of some major materials are already recycled, but as a per-
centage of  total  consumption recycling has been static or declining, and only a
small portion of post-consumer waste is recycled. Present rates of recycling can be
increased substantially to supply a limited, but important, fraction  of our  total
needs for materials.
   •  A number of Government practices deviate from the principle that  the rate of
recycling  should  reflect informed decisions  made on the basis of the true cost of
materials. The 94th  Congress acted  to eliminate such practices as: discrimination
against  recycled  materials  in  procurement  specifications; possible discrimination
against  recyclables in regulated freight rates; and a variety  of institutional barriers
which cause localities to miss recycling opportunities.
   •  The Commission recommends that Congress take further action to  implement
the true-cost-of-materials principle.   It should internalize the cost of disposing of
materials  by means  such as  mandatory deposits on  beverage  containers, excise
taxes on nonreturnable containers, and product disposal charges on other consumer
packaging and on paper.
   •  Due to the  absence of compelling evidence for its continuation, the Commis-
sion recommends repeal of the percentage depletion allowance for minerals.
   •  The Commission recommends that Congress  avoid actions that are contrary
to the true-cost-of-materials principle, such as new  or extensive Federal  funding of
systems to recover resources from waste.

   These important findings and recommendations should be well considered by all
those who are concerned with effective conservation of resources and protection of
the environment.

                                             -SHELDON MEYERS
                                            Deputy Assistant Administrator
                                            for Solid Waste Management
                                             U.S. Environmental Protection
                                              Agency

-------
    NATIONAL COMMISSION ON SUPPLIES AND
                        SHORTAGES

DONALD B. RICE, President, The Rand Corporation
  Chairman
BILL BROCK, United States Senator (Tennessee)
ALAN GREENSPAN, Chairman, Council of Economic Advisers
HENDRIK S. HOUTHAKKER, Professor of Economics, Harvard University
GEORGE KOZMETSKY, Dean, College of Business Administration and
  Graduate School of Business, University of Texas
JAMES T. LYNN, Director, Office of Management and Budget
THOMAS M. REES,  Member,  U.S. House  of  Representatives (23rd
  District, California)
L. WILLIAM SEIDMAN, Assistant to the President for Economic Affairs
WILLIAM E. SIMON, Secretary of the Treasury
  Vice Chairman
]. WILLIAM STANTON,  Member,  U.S.  House of Representatives  (llth
  District, Ohio)
PHILIP H. TREZISE, Senior Fellow, The Brookings Institution
JOHN  V. TUNNEY, United States Senator (California)
NAT WEINBERG, Director, Special  Projects, UAW (Retired)

-------
                           CHAPTER 8

                          Recycling
   PUBLIC LAW93-426 directs the Commission to report on  private and
public practices which affect the supply of materials and on alternative
actions to increase their availability.
   Recycling affects the available supply  of materials. Sizeable amounts
of some major materials  already are recycled, but as a percentage of
total consumption, recycling has been static or  declining in  America,
and  only a small portion  of postconsumer waste is recycled. Not all of
the materials consumed can be economically recycled but present rates
of recycling  can  be  increased substantially,  to  supply  a  limited but
important fraction of our total needs for  materials.
   The term "urban ore" has been applied to the materials used up and
discarded by consumers. Some economic considerations discourage the
recycling of "urban ore" in much  the same way  that similar considera-
tions discourage  the  exploitation  of virgin ore  deposits. Moreover, a
number of (k)vernment practices effectively (if inadvertently) discour-
age  recycling. Such practices are deviations from the principle that the
rate of recycling should reflect informed decisions made on  the basis of
the  true cost of materials. Within  the  last year, Congress has  taken
legislative action to eliminate discrimination against recycled  materials in
procurement specifications, possible discrimination against recydables in
regulated freight rates, and  a  variety of institutional barriers  which
cause localities to miss recycling opportunities. Further action should be
taken in furtherance  of the true-cost-of-materials principle—for  exam-
ple,  repeal of tax subsidies to producers of virgin materials and the
imposition of disposal  charges and  refundable deposits on containers
and  paper products.
            THE POTENTIAL  FOR  RECYCLING

  The  American economy uses approximately 4.5  billion  tons of
nonfood materials each year. A large  fraction of current consumption
of major materials is met from recycling. However, as Table 15 shows,
the portion of materials demand met from  recycling is static or
declining  overall— and  most recycling  comes from scrap  created by
industrial  production and fabrication  processes rather  than from
materials which consumers discard.
  Proponents claim four major benefits from increased recycling in the
United States.
  1. Increasing  demands on the world's virgin  resources are  making

                                                                155

-------
              TABLE 15—Total Recycling as a Percent of Consumption
                                       Steel  Aluminum  Copper  Paper
 1955                                    51       21        53      26
 1965                                    50       17        61      21
 1973                                    51       18        55      21
             Postconsumer Waste Recycling as a Percent of Consumption
 1973                                    16        3        19      14
  Sources: Statistics tor steel, aluminum, and copper recycling are derived from United States Department of the
 Interior, Bureau of Mines Minrrtib Yparknok: statistics for aluminum and copper recycling are limited to purchased
 scrap. Statistics tor paper are also limited to purchased scrap: they are taken from American Paper Institute,
 Slitli\fit\ it/ Pn/irr and Pajit^tifitird.


 their extraction more and more costly in terms of capital requirements
 and environmental degradation.  Recycling material in postconsumer
 waste can  reduce those demands. Once  such material is discarded and
 buried, it becomes much more difficult to recover economically.
   2. The production of manufactured products from recycled materials
 generally results in a "significant'saving of  energy. For example, energy
 equivalent to 6,700 kwh is required  to produce a  ton of  steel  from
 virgin resources, and only one-third of  that  amount is. required  to
 manufacture a  ton from scrap; 70,000  kwh are  required to extract  a
 ton of aluminum from virgin resources,  and only one-twentieth of that
 amount  to extract it from scrap; substantially more  energy is required
 to manufacture a ton  of paper  from virgin resources than from scrap.'
   3.  Recycling  provides  a  domestic source  of  materials.  This reduces
 the political uncertainties of foreign sources of supply and the adverse
 impact of the demand for imported materials on the Nation's balance
 of trade.                                       '
   4. A  fourth major benefit is  beyond the narrowly  defined  bounds of
 materials policy. Solid waste handling accounts for  the second largest
 expenditure of our major  cities; cities can expect a 20 to 30 percent
 increase  in  real disposal costs over the next 10 years; landfill sites are
 becoming scarce in heavily  populated areas and disposal  presents air
 and water pollution problems. One potential by-product of recycling is
 a  smaller waste stream whose constituent  parts are  more  easily
 managed.
   To what extent can increased recycling  of industrial and  postconsu-
 mer solid waste  provide these benefits?
   It  has been  assumed in the  past that all  the industrial  waste
 economically available  is being recycled. This  assumption  is based on'
 the fact that much  industrial  scrap is high-grade and  available at
 convenient  locations.  There has been relatively  little study of actual
 rates  of  recycling industrial  solid waste,  however, and there is a large
 new source of such waste about which even less  is known  Under the
 Clean Air  Act  and  the Federal Water  Pollution  Control Act  the
 Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) has promulgated regulations
 which require that materials  formerly  discharged  as air and  water
 pollutants  must  now  be collected  and  handled as solid  waste. The
 mineral concentrations in many such  wastes exceed those in many ores
 now being processed.2
156

-------
     TABLE 16—Potential Additional Materials from Recycling of Postconsumer Waste
                      (percent of domestic consumption)

                                         Steel   Aluminum   Copper  Paper
Postconsumer waste (Population Commission,
1972)
Municipal solid waste (EPA, 1974)
Municipal solid waste (FEA, 1974)
2
7
4
15
8
6
10
5
—
—
14
14
  Sources: Fischman and Landsberg, "Adequacy of Nonfuel Minerals and Forest Resources," in Commission on
Population Growth and the American Future, Research Report1, Vol. 3, 98 (1972). These estimates are based on
projections of the amounts of materials likely to be in use in the year 2000 and of the useful life (and "retirement"
rate) of such materials.
  EPA, Second Report to Congress; Resource Recovery and Source Reduction 14 (1974). These estimates are based on
EPA calculations of the amounts of materials in  municipal solid waste collected in standard metropolitan statistical
areas during 1971; recovery efficiencies of 30% lor paper and 80% for other materials are assumed.
  Federal Energy Administration, Report hi Congress: Energy Conservation Stud\ 83 (1974). These estimates are based
on calculations by Resource Planning Associates of the amounts of materiafs in municipal solid waste collected in
standard metropolitan statistical areas during 1970; recovery efficiencies of 80% for steel, H0% for aluminum and
30% for paper are assumed.


   There has been much more study of municipally-collected postconsu-
mer solid waste, including some  80 million tons of metals, paper, and
glass.  At  present  less than 10  percent of this material  is  recycled.3
Excluding the  postconsumer wastes  that are  discarded  in  remote
locations, lost in litter, or are unusable for technical  reasons, it has been
estimated  that recycling  the remainder could  contribute significantly  to
the Nation's supply of materials. Three recent estimates,  shown  in
Table 16, may be regarded as  "ball-park" figures.
   The estimates in Table 16  are consistent with  the  independent
assessments  made  by the Commission  staff:  ferrous scrap potentially
recoverable from  municipal solid waste  has  been put  at 4  or  5 percent
of total consumption by industry sources; skyrocketing costs of plant and
equipment, energy, and  raw materials will provide substantial incentives
to  increase  the recycling of aluminum;  the chances of  increased
recycling of copper are  more  modest."  It has  also been estimated that
increased recovery of resources (both materials  and energy) from
postconsumer  solid waste could  save  energy equivalent to 521,000
barrels of oil per day—7 percent of all the fuel consumed  by  utilities  in
1970.5  Balance-of-trade effects would admittedly be modest, but in the
right  direction.  Currently  available  resource recovery  systems can
readily reduce by 65 percent the amount of solid waste which must be
disposed of.6


            OBSTACLES AND OPPORTUNITIES

   If recycling is economically  beneficial, why isn't  more material being
recycled? The economic value of some  material in postconsumer waste
is not as  high as  the  cost of exploiting  it, often  for  much the same
reasons that  value of virgin material is insufficient  to  justify exploita-
tion. The  material in some postconsumer waste may not be sufficiently
concentrated to  be of economic  value—for example, roadside litter.  Or
the  material  may  be  so  far  removed from processing plants that
transporation costs would be prohibitive—for example,  waste  in  remote

                                                                       157

-------
rural locations. Not only may the positive economic value of material in
postconsumer waste be insufficient, but its negative economic value may
also be  insufficient.  The economic value  of recycling  material  in
postconsumer waste is the sum of the money realized from recovery of
the materials and the money saved from not having to dispose of the
material. While actual postcollection disposal costs in the Northeast may
run to $15 a ton and provide a strong incentive to recycle rather than
dispose, such costs in  the  West can be as low as $1  or  $2 per ton and
thus afford little incentive.
   However, quite apart  from  these market considerations,  some
Government practices discourage recycling: these practices  deviate from
the principle that the rate  of recycling should reflect informed decisions
made on  the basis  of  the  true costs of materials.  Until  1975,
congressional enactments  which have dealt explicitly  with recycling7
have been limited to authorizing  further study  or allocating  Federal
money for technical research,  development and demonstrations.*
Recently, the  Congress  has  been giving  much closer  attention  to
recycling.                                 ,

Federal Funding of Demonstration Projects
   The 94th Congress considered and rejected several recommendations
for  Federal funding of projects to demonstrate the  recovery  of
resources from solid waste. A House Committee marked up legislation
which would have authorized loan guarantees for projects to  demon-
strate the recovery of resources from solid waste in amounts up to $2.5
billion.  A  House-Senate  conference committee recommended an au-
thorization of $300 million in  loan guarantees to produce  energy from
biomass  (defined  as  urban  and  industrial waste,  crops, animal waste,
sewage sludge), and an authorization of  $5  million for a price-support
program to demonstrate the production  of fuels and energy-intensive
products from solid waste. And four House committees reported a bill
authorizing loan guarantees in varying amount up to  $3.5 billion for
projects to demonstrate the production of synthetic fuels from domestic
resources, including solid waste.
   None of these  bills (is  an  effective approach  to  the  problem  of
  *The Solid Waste Disposal Act, as amended by the Resource Recovery Act of 1970,
does require EPA to establish guidelines for  solid waste collection,  separation,
disposal, and recovery systems. Essentially, the guidelines are binding only on Federal
agencies which dispose of solid waste. Under the Act, EPA has promulgated
guidelines which:
  (1) Require a deposit of at least  5(Z on  all beverage  containers sold in Federal
     facilities;
  (2) Require any Federal facility disposing of  100 tons or more per day of solid
     waste to separate and recover materials or energy, or both, from it;
  (3) Require Federal facilities to separate at the source, collect and sell high-grade
     paper for the purpose of  recycling (in offices of over 100 workers) used
     newspapers (on residential facilities of more than 500 families), and corrugated
     containers (from any commercial establishment generating  10,or more tons per
     month).
  Federal agencies may determine not to comply  with these guidelines Upon a finding
that compliance would be economically impracticable.
158

-------
increasing recycling. It does not appear that increased recycling is being
thwarted by any lack of government-supported research and develop-
ment. R&D programs on resource recovery are currently maintained by
the Office of Solid Waste Management Programs in EPA (which has an
appropriation of $15.7  million  for fiscal  1977),  by  the  Solid  Waste
Division of the Bureau  of Mines (which administers programs funded
at $5.5 million for fiscal  1977),  and  by the Energy Research  and
Development Administration (ERDA), which has appropriations of $4.6
million for its Urban Waste Technology Branch and $5.2 million  for its
fuels-from-biomass program  in fiscal  1977.  There are  areas  which
warrant continuing  technological research,  but there  is a  broad
consensus that inadequate technology is not the major (or even a major)
restraint on recycling. The House  Committee on  Government Opera-
tions has reported that:

   Representatives of municipalities, of State  Government, of the
   Federal Government,  of private  industry and of financial institu-
   tions are  in basic agreement that the technology of resource
   recovery is now available.8

Besides,  until recently  most  recycling  of municipal solid  waste  was
accomplished by a low-technology method—requiring users to separate
their trash. The preliminary results  of demonstration projects currently
assisted by EPA suggest that  source separation is still a  cost-effective
means of resource recovery.
   The availability of Federal money for demonstration projects can  lead
local governments to uneconomic decisions: only by adopting new high-
technology, capital-intensive systems can cities transfer their costs  to the
Federal Government. To subsidize  the recovery of energy,  but not of
materials, from solid  waste would  be to compound pressures for the
inefficient use of resources. (For example, use of old newspapers as  fuel
is  significantly less energy-efficient than recycling of the same newspa-
pers into newsprint.5') Furthermore, Federal investment decisions  can
be uneconomic and counter-productive—a substantial risk in any system
which is (necessarily) driven by political considerations.
   The EPA  demonstration  program,  perhaps because of i& modest
size, has been able to avoid political  pressures to a large degree; the
program appears  to  be more successful than other Federally-funded
demonstration programs included  in a  recent study sponsored by the
Experimental Technology Incentives Program of the  National Bureau
of Standards. This study concluded that demonstration projects have a
narrow scope for effective use and that diffusion of the technology to
be  demonstrated depends  on "market pull"  rather than  "technology
push".10
   Some  high-technology local projects  for resource  recovery are in
operation or under construction without Federal  support, and  invest-
ment bankers have expressed  interest in  financing other projects. "The
House Committee on Government Operations has concluded that:

  Congress should not  authorize  Federal financial assistance...(or)
   Federal guarantees of municipal or State  bonds...to  finance re-
  source recovery or other municipal solid waste disposal systems.12

                                                               159

-------
  These considerations  all suggest that  Government funding of  re-
source recovery  demonstrations  should not  be increased substantially
above its present modest size. The Resource Conservation and Recovery
Act of 1976 recognizes these considerations by providing that EPA may
not fund a full-scale resource recovery facility unless it finds:
     • that  the  facility  will demonstrate at full scale  a new  or
  significantly  improved  technology or  process, a practical and
  significant improvement in solid waste management practice, or the
  technical  feasibility and cost-effectiveness  of an existing but  un-
  proven process;
     • that the  facility will not duplicate any other facility on  which
  construction has already begun; and
     • that  the facility  is  not  likely to be constructed or operated
  without such funding.
To the extent  that  solid  waste disposal costs  present overwhelming
financial  problems  to  cities which justify  Federal  assistance,  these
problems would best be met through some form of general  revenue
sharing, and not through  a system  of financial  assistance  which would
require  a city  to  adopt something  other  than the least expensive
solution.
  The Commission  opposes Federal funding of systems to recover
  energy or materials from waste, whether by means of grants, loan
  guarantees, or price supports; exception should be made only for
  the  limited number of systems which possess the characteristics of
  true demonstration projects.

Tax Subsidies
  There is a broad consensus that lack of long-term, stable demand is a
major deterrent to utilization of resources in postconsumer waste. The
degree to which tax preferences  to  the consumption  of virgin  over
recycled materials undermine  long-term, stable demand for  recycled
materials  has not  yet been  adequately calculated; however, scattered
pieces of evidence indicate  that such preferences have  a  substantial
undermining effect.  The 94th  Congress considered proposals to repeal
tax  subsidies for  the consumption of virgin materials and to create
countervailing tax  subsidies for the consumption of recycled materials.*
  *Amendment No. 1882, proposed by Senator Haskell to H.R. 10612 and rejected
by the full Senate, would have effectively repealed a variety of tax subsidies, including
the percentage depletion  allowance for minerals and capital  gains treatment for
timber. H.R.  10612, the Tax Reform Act of 1976, as reported by the Senate Finance
Committee, would have alloWed a taxpayer, as a credit against tax, a percentage of the
qualifying amount of recyclable solid waste material which he purchases and recycles
in the  U.S.; the amount of purchases Which qualifies  would be the amount which
exceeds 75% of annual  average purchases  in the preceding three  years; the
percentage allowed would equal Vz of the percent  of the depletion allowance for
metals (precious metals are excluded),  10% for textile and paper waste, and 5% for
glass and plastics; recyclable solid waste materials would be defined as postconsumer
solid waste and purchased scrap (if the latter is from fabricators who do not produce
their own feed  material). The full Senate deleted this provision. A similar tax credit,
proposed by  the House Ways and Means Committee, in the  Resource Conservation
and Conversion Act of 1975, was defeated last year.

160

-------
  The Federal Government gives  tax subsidies  to the consumption of
virgin materials both  by allowing the deduction from income of a fixed
percentage of the value of mineral production* and by allowing capital
gains treatment of income derived from the increase in the' value of
standing timber.
  Minerals—The percentage depletion allowance in particular has been
the subject of extensive study. The Treasury  Department has estimated
that, largely  as a result of this tax subsidy, mineral industries  have an
effective tax  rate of about 25 percent of total  net income, compared
with 43 percent for other manufacturing industries.13
  Percentage depletion has encouraged the  growth  of large vertically-
integrated materials companies which shelter  their income by maintain-
ing high  prices  for their virgin material input and  allocating  their
profits to virgin material production.14 The dominant materials compa-
nies are structured,  both  physically  and institutionally,  to  use wholly-
owned virgin materials as their primary  feed. They also make routine
use  of  high-grade  scrap produced in their  own  plants and the
manufacturing and fabricating processes of their customers.  But usually
they purchase postconsumer scrap  only  to  respond  to peaks in the
demand for  their product;  accordingly, their  demand for  recycled
material  fluctuates over a wide  range. Physical  reasons alone do not
account for  such  a structure: postconsumer scrap has the advantage
over virgin  materials of being found in  bulk at the  point  of ultimate
consumption;  there are certainly substantial  problems in preparing
lower grades of scrap for industrial use, but there are also substantial
problems in  preparing lower  grades of  virgin materials. However,
industry has  devoted great effort to beneficiating low-grade ores and
little or no effort to recovering resources in postconsumer waste.
  The  American  steel industry,  for example,  is dominated  by  eight
vertically-integrated  companies  which accounted for  75  percent of
production  in  1974;  more  than  85 percent  of the ore  which they
consumed  came from company-owned  sources.15  The industry has
consistently  raised  the price  at which it sells  itself ore, regardless of
fluctuations in the demand for steel; on the other hand, the  price of
scrap purchased has  fluctuated sharply with demand (see Table 17). In
recent years,  the  export price  of No.  1   heavy melting scrap has
regularly exceeded  the domestic  price; since foreign  purchasers  must
bear transportation charges as well, it is probable that the domestic steel
industry substantially under-values scrap. It has been estimated that in
the United States  the effect of tax preferences more  than accounts for
  *Mineral companies  have the option of using the same type  of cost depletion
which is available to other industries—i.e., they may divide the original cost of
developing the mineral deposit  by the number of tons to be produced, and deduct
this amount as part of the cost of each ton mined. In 1960, cost depletion accounted
for less than l()'/f of the depletion taken by the minerals industry. Miller, "Percentage
Depletion and the Level of Domestic Mineral Production," 15 Natural Resources]. 242
(1975).

                                                                  Ifil

-------
         TABLE \~7-Steel Production and Ore and Scrap Prices, 1950-1975


Year

1950
1951
1952
1953
1954
1955
1956
1957
1958
1959
I960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
Sources: Figures lor steel
Hr{it,il. The price ol ore rel

Steel Produced
(millions of tons)

72
79
68
80
63
85
83
80
60
69
71
66
71
76
85
93
90
84
92
93
91
87
92
111
110
80
produced are those ol shipments in Ame

Price of Ore
($/ton)

4.99
5.46
6.09
6.76
6.99
7.12
7.75
8.33
8.39
8.69
8.79
8.99
8.84
9.22
9.52
9.33
9.49
9.92
10.21
10.341
10.80
11.55
12.20
12.84
16.34
21.41
rican Iron £ Steel
presents the average value ol domestic ore at the mine, per
Composite Price
of No. 1 Heavy
Melting Scrap
($/ton)
35
43
42
40
29
40
53
47
38
38
33
36
28
27
36
34
31
28
26
31
45
35
37
58
109
72
Institute, .-tiinnnl MdlHlifrtl
KI-OSS ton: this price and
the difference between the cost of producing a ton of steel from scrap,
and the lower cost of producing it from virgin material.*
  Econometric studies (performed  for EPA)  have concluded  that the
repeal of tax  subsidies for the consumption  of virgin  materials would
increase the current price of virgin  materials  only slightly; the resulting
increases in  rates of recycling were estimated at about 1 to 5 percent."1
However, these  studies  of  marginal price  effects  are  based  on  an
historical record which reveals  that there is relatively little price elasticity
of demand for postconsumer scrap.** Thus, they assume the continued
 . *See EPA, Second Report to Congress: Resource Recovery mid Source Reduction 35 (1974).
The cost of a ton of steel using pig iron was estimated to be $40.50; the cost of a ton
of steel using scrap was $43.00; the tax benefits to virgin  iron ore and coal exceed
$2.50. This calculation is confirmed by more recent cost estimates in Cosman, "Studies
of Recycling Problems  in Selected Industries,"  in Commission  Document, Additional
Background Studies.

  **See, e.g., Charles River Associates, Inc. A Study of Ihe Ferrous Scrap Market -Diiring
tin-  Shortage Period o/ 1973-1974 (June  1976)", p. 7-4. While the demand for

162                                                                      *

-------
 existence of an historical industry structure based at least in part upon
 the same tax subsidies. Only time can tell the extent to which repeal of
 these subsidies would change  industry structure.  Recently, materials
 companies have demonstrated that they  will integrate vertically into
 scrap sources of supply, given the right economic circumstances.17
   The argument that repeal of tax subsidies will increase the rate of
 recycling  is supported  by  incomplete  evidence.  But the evidence to
 support continuation of such tax subsidies is even weaker.
   In the  past  it has  been  politically  difficult to  repeal existing tax
 subsidies,  such  as the percentage depletion allowance for minerals. In
 spite of this history, the Congress terminated the percentage depletion
 allowance for major oil companies in 1975. (The House voted, 248-163,
 to  repeal the entire allowance; the Senate, by a vote of 47-41, retained
 the allowance for independent producers.)*
   Repeal  of the percentage depletion  allowance for  minerals would
 probably make little difference  in  the  near-term  availability of virgin
 materials: the allowance may only be taken on one-half of profits; thus,
 if a mineral deposit is  not very profitable, the allowance affords little
 incentive to produce. It now appears that most depletion is taken at the
 full statutory rate; i.e., on non-marginal deposits which would be mined
 without regard to any tax subsidy.  (For example, if depletion is  taken
 on a copper mine at the full statutory rate [15 percent], then the  profit
 on  the mine   must be  equal  to at least  30 percent of the value of
 production.)18
   Repeal of tax subsidies could  affect the long-term availability of
 domestic  minerals  by lowering the after-tax return  on capital  from
 domestic mineral exploitation.  Lowering the return  on capital of the
 mineral industries  relative to other industries would  not be entirely
 negative:  the   percentage  depletion allowance for minerals currently
 distorts resource allocation  toward  capital-  (and energy-) intensive
 exploitation of lower-grade  domestic ore. Federal  Trade Commission
 figures suggest that in recent years  before- and after-tax rates of  profit
postconsumer scrap is relatively inelastic, the supply of postconsumer scrap is highly
price-elastic. Ibid. The Treasury Department has concluded that:
  most scrap or waste that can be economically used is already  collected. The cost
  of substantially expanding collection is prohibitive. Therefore, an increase  in
  recycling is not prevented by any tax incentive-induced reduction in the sale price
  of competitive virgin materials, but by the  costs  of collection.  Administration
  Position, Hearings on Certain  Provisions of the Tax Reform Bill (H.R. 10612)
  before the Senate Committee on Finance, July 20, 1976.
The premise of the Treasury Department argument is not supported by the evidence.
Industry  has historically  been  capable of recycling far higher percentages of
aluminum and paper scrap, for example. See Table  1. An industry-sponsored study
estimates that scrap dealers now have in-place capacity to process more than twice the
previous record  annual demand for ferrous scrap. See Battelle Columbus Laborato-
ries, The Prncewing Capacity of the Ferrous Scrap Industry  (August 10, 1976).

  *C/. The National  Democratic Plat/arm 1976, p. 48: "Economic  inequities created by
subsidies  for  virgin materials to the  disadvantage  of recycled materials must be
eliminated. Depletion allowances and unequal  freight rates serve to discourage the
growing numbers of businesses engaged in recycling efforts."

                                                                     163

-------
 on  stockholders' equity  for corporations in  the mining industry have
 been substantially greater than the rate of profit for all manufacturing
 corporations.1" The mining industry has  urged  in defense  of the
 mineral depletion allowance that it will  need to raise vast amounts of
 capital over the coming years.2"  But the industry has  made no attempt
 to demonstrate that  the  (Government should favor its  efforts to raise
 capital over the efforts of  other industries.  Tax equity and economic
 efficiency would be better served if the Federal (Government considered
 the needs of the mineral  industry  for  tax  relief in raising capital*
 together with the needs of other  industries, and  not as a class apart.
   If tax subsidies were repealed, prices  would bear the  full burden of
 stimulating virgin mineral  production.  Congressional  opponents of
 percentage depletion for oil and  gas argued that prices  rather than
 subsidies are the appropriate method of stimulating production.21
   The  mining industry has also  urged  that the  continuation of tax
 subsidies protects  the  national  interest  in an  assured supply of
 minerals.22  But  the  cost of tax subsidies  is substantial:  it has  been
 estimated that  the revenue  loss  from the percentage depletion allow-
 ance  for minerals  will exceed $850 million  in  fiscal year  1977.2"
 Because the percentage depletion allowance for minerals offers the least
 incentive to the exploitation of marginal deposits, it is not well  designed
 to increase  mineral supplies. The Treasury  Department estimated in
 1969 that the percentage depletion allowance for oil and gas cost about
' $1.6 billion in tax revenue for additional  reserves  worth  only $0.15
 billion."4  The  cost  of tax subsidies as  a  method of  protecting the
 national interest in an assured supply of minerals should be measured
 against costs of other  methods of  preventing disruption  of foreign
 supply—such  as stockpiling. The  latter  method  may be  many times
 cheaper.**
   In sum, the cost of the percentage depletion allowance for minerals is
 substantial in terms of lost  revenue.  While the marginal  price  effect of
 this tax subsidy appears to be negligible, it is a strong  incentive to an
 industry structure  which  is inimical  to the use  of resources in
 postconsumer waste.  The benefits  derived from the  percentage deple-
 tion allowance do  not appear to be proportionate to the cost.

   Timber—The consequences of capital gains treatment for timber have
 been  studied  less thoroughly than  the  consequences  of  percentage
   *COMMISSIONER WEINBERG: If the public is to provide capital for private
 firms through  tax subsidies,  it (i.e., the  government as the representative of the
 public) should obtain  an equity interest in the firm in return for its capital
 contribution. (See colloquy on  this point between Mr. Charles Carlisle, Vice President,
 St. Joe Mineral Company and myself, Commission Document, Public Hearings on
 Problems oj Supplies and Shortages.)

   **The Commission has sought the views of the Department of the Interior and the
 Bureau of Mines on this subject. The  Assistant Secretary of the Interior for Energy
 and Minerals has informed  the Commission  that "quantitative answers will be
 exceedingly difficult to derive. It is my firm judgment that the depletion allowance is
 fully justified, notwithstanding the present difficulty in quantitative justification." See
 letter of November 8, 1976 from Dr. William L. Fisher to Dr.  George C. Eads in
 Commission Document, Public  Hearing on Problems of Materials Supplies and Shortages.

 164                                                                 »

-------
depletion for  minerals. There are some similarities. The Treasury
Department  has estimated that the  lumber industry  has a  tax rate of
only  30 percent,  largely  as  a result of capital  gains treatment  for
timber;25 the revenue  loss from  this  tax  subsidy  will be  about $200
million in fiscal year  1977.2li  Treasury has  identified capital  gains
treatment for timber as a cause of the shift in ownership of timberland
toward large,  vertically-integrated  corporations  which shelter their
income by maintaining high timber  prices.27 The  twenty largest paper
companies accounted for 65 percent of all the paper and paperboard
made  in the United States during 1974; eighteen of these companies
had Umber holdings totalling  37 million  acres in the United States and
4  million acres in  Canada.28 The Treasury  Department  reported in
1969 that:
   The  tax advantage  of capital gains treatment  of timber accrues
   mainly to  large  corporations and high-income  individuals.  Small
   corporations with taxable income  less  than $25,000 do not benefit
   from  the  capital gains  provision.  In  1965 there were 13,251
   corporate  returns filed  in  the  lumber and paper industries. Of
   these, five companies reported  51.3 percent  of  the long-term
   capital gains.2"
Although it  is difficult to assign  a  causal relationship on  the  present
evidence, the rate  of paper recycling in  the United States has declined
from 35 percent to  21  percent since capital gains  treatment for timber
was enacted  (over President  Roosevelt's veto) in  1944.3" The major
consumers of recycled paper are, for the  most part, not  the largest
paper companies  but  a handful  of companies without major timber
holdings.31 The industry's  demand  for recycled  paper is so unstable
that waste paper  prices  fell  during  1974  from  $60 to $5 per ton;
sometimes a  buyer could not be found at any price.
   However,  there are complicating  factors  in assessing  the conse-
quences of  capital gains treatment  for  timber, such as industry's
extensive cutting of Umber from public  lands.32 The matter is further
complicated  by  the  fact that  capital gains treatment  for  timber is an
extension of a more general provision  of the tax code applicable to
other long-lived assets;  the Commission has not examined the question
of equitable  application of the capital gains provisions to timber versus
other  assets.  Nonetheless,  the  Congress should  require  a thorough
justification of this tax subsidy, before determining to continue it.
   Countervailing Tax Proposal—During  the 94th Congress, the House
Ways and Means Committee  and  the  Senate  Finance Committee each
reported proposals to create a countervailing tax subsidy in the  form of
a  tax credit  for purchase of recyclable solid waste  materials. These
proposals would have substantially increased, rather than reduced,  the
subsidy of materials consumption  by the general tax  rolls.  It has been
estimated that the Senate Finance Committee bill  would have reduced
budget receipts by  an estimated $345 million in fiscal 1981.33 According
to past estimates, tax subsidies for virgin material  consumption are an
inefficient means  of expanding the supply  of minerals;  there  is no
reason  to suppose  that a tax credit  for the purchase of recycled
materials would be a more efficient expenditure of tax dollars. Apart

                                                                165

-------
from these general considerations, both  proposals would have allowed
substantial windfalls in  the form of credits  for  the  recycling of high-
grade purchased industrial scrap.
  In the absence  of compelling evidence  for its continuation,  the
  Commission recommends the repeal  of the percentage depletion
  allowance for minerals;  the Commission  opposes the creation of
  new tax subsidies for the consumption  of recycled materials.*

Internalizing Disposal Costs
  Governments discourage  the recycling  of containers and  paper
products by  assessing the cost  of discarding such  materials  against
general  revenues rather than  against the price  of the containers and
paper products. As recently as 1960, 95  percent of the soft drinks and
50 percent of the beer were sold in returnable containers; the price of
the  beverage included  the  cost  of distributing containers, collecting
them after use, cleaning them  and placing them  back in service.34 Now
the  most common  form  of beverage container is the  no deposit-no
return bottle or can; the  price does  not reflect collection and disposal
costs, which are borne not by the consumer but by society at large.
  The 94th Congress considered legislation  requiring  EPA to establish
standards  of control for products which  "may use an  unreasonable
amount  of energy or of materials identified  by the President as critical
to national  security  or in short supply."  Another bill would have
imposed a schedule of national solid  waste disposal charges on the sale
or transfer, at the bulk production level, of rigid consumer containers
(at 0.50  per container),  and of flexible consumer packaging and paper
(at  1.30  per lb.); the charge would have been introduced over  a ten-
year period, starting at  zero and increasing  by 10 percent per year; it
would have been reduced by the  percent  of secondary materials content
in the product. A third bill would have  required a refundable deposit
of at least five cents on carbonated beverage containers, to take effect in
five  years.
  COMMISSIONERS GREENSPAN, HOUTHAKKER, LYNN, SEIDMAN, AND
SIMON: Repeal of the percentage depletion allowance would improve economic
efficiency by eliminating an artificial bias toward virgin material use, but would raise
the effective corporation income tax rate. Repeal of percentage depletion should be
accompanied by a compensating reduction in general corporation  income tax rates
sufficient to offset the revenue effect of removing the depletion allowance. However,
this does not imply  that we believe the present level of corporate taxation to be
appropriate.
  COMMISSIONER WEINBERG: This recommendation should have included a call
for ending the  capital gains tax subsidy for standing timber. The only  significant
argument advanced  against  such a recommendation was that since capital gains
treatment applies generally,  timber should not be singled out for its elimination. In
my view, favoritism to capital gains income over earned income  should be ended
across the board. In any event, timber harvesting has never been eligible  for capital
gains treatment under general provisions of the tax code. Congress singled out timber
to receive-special capital gains  treatment in the Revenue Act of 1943. In his veto
message, Franklin Roosevelt (himself a  tree farmer) argued that timber should
continue to be treated as a crop and its sale treated as ordinary income. I believe he
was right, even though his veto was overridden.

166

-------
  The first bill is inconsistent with the general principle that the rate of
recycling should reflect the true  costs of materials; the bill proposes a
regulatory approach similar to that of the Clean Air Act or the Federal
Water Pollution Control Act. These acts establish regulatory schemes
which  require businesses  to install the best demonstrated or available
control technology. The definition of such technology for a multiplicity
of industries and  plants  has proved  a  difficult regulatory  task.
Businesses  have  delayed  substantial costs by  engaging in protracted
litigation against  regulations.35 Perhaps such an  approach should be
reserved for those situations where it is  difficult, if  not impossible, to
estimate external  costs. It is  relatively easy to estimate  disposal costs.
  The second  bill would incorporate disposal costs  into the  prices of
products. It would leave to individual businesses the decision on how to
increase  recycling or reduce  waste in order to obtain  the  greatest
progress at the least cost.  Accumulating tax liability would eliminate an
incentive to  use  litigation as  a delaying tactic. The bill  would cover
packaging and paper products which make up almost one-half of the
total waste stream and  80 percent of all product-type wastes.  A study
prepared for EPA suggests  that such a system of product charges could
double present  rates of paper recycling and  provide a marginal
incentive for more efficient use of materials in production.3"  Adminis-
tration costs have been  projected at about one-half of 1 percent of the
revenue raised.37  Gradual imposition of a disposal charge would  allow
time for implementing regulations  embodying suggested "fine-tunirifg"
changes, such  as adding the  costs of complying with environmental
controls on  disposal to the  base cost, or establishing a separate rate of
charge for plastic containers, such as that proposed by the City of New
York.  It would  also be appropriate  to  exempt  consumer packaging
which  carried a refundable deposit from such a disposal charge.
  A mandatory deposit on carbonated beverage containers, proposed in
the third bill, would also  internalize external  costs. Such  a deposit has
been  tested in the  State of Oregon where  it has  greatly stimulated
recycling  and  reduced the amount of  roadside litter while  leaving
beverage prices  essentially  unchanged.:)H Detailed  projections of the
national impact of a mandatory deposit system have  been  made by the
Department of Commerce (which is opposed  to such a system), by the
Federal Energy Administration (which has not taken  a position) and by
the Environmental Protection Agency (which favors such a system). The
average of capital cost  estimates by Commerce and by FEA is $l-$4
billion; all three agencies predict  a  modest net gain in employment, but
with a shift of 40,000 to  80,000 jobs  from container  industries to
retailing and  distribution. Given a 90  percent  return rate   (not
unrealistic in light of Oregon's experience), all three agencies  predict
energy savings of 150-200 billion Btu per year, somewhat less than one
day's  national energy consumption; EPA predicts savings of about 13
billion pounds of raw  materials.  Commerce predicts a reduction in
municipal solid waste of  slightly less  than  5  percent by weight;  EPA
predicts a reduction of about 20 percent by volume  in municipal  solid
waste;  FEA  predicts that the value of materials thus removed  from the
waste stream would  have no substantial effect on  municipal decisions to

                                                                167

-------
landfill or to recover resources.3!i Sweden is putting into effect a similar
mandatory deposit system for automobiles: there is a tax of SwKr 300
($65) on the purchase of a car;  the tax is refundable when  the car is
turned in  to a scrap  yard.  This system  merits further study in  the
United States.*
  The Commission recommends that the Government take steps to
  internalize the cost of disposing of materials; means of accomplish-
  ing this include mandatory deposits on beverage containers, excise
  taxes on non-returnable containers, and product disposal charges
  on other consumer packaging and on paper.

Freight Rates
  Discriminatory  freight rates  have been  cited as  a factor depressing
the  demand  for  recycled materials. The evidence supporting this
assertion is  mixed, at best. A  1973'study  concluded that  freight rates
represented a substantial fraction of the cost of using scrap iron and
wastepaper, but not of aluminum scrap; and  that the ratio of railroad
revenue to variable costs was higher for scrap iron than for iron ore,
but  lower  for  aluminum scrap than ingots and for wastepaper than
woodpulp.40 A 1974 study concluded that, when directly compared,
rates for transporting  scrap  iron were higher than  for iron ore, and
rates for wastepaper higher than for wood chips; however, rates were
lower  for wastepaper and scrap  iron when compared  on  a chemically
equivalent basis (i.e., comparing the  cost of transporting enough virgin
materials to make one ton of steel or paperboard  against  the  costs of
transporting enough secondary materials to make the same ton).41
  The  Railroad  Revitalization and Regulatory  Reform Act of 1976
(together with the prior Regional Railroad Reorganization Act) requires
the  Interstate Commerce Commission to investigate  the rate structure
for transporting recyclable materials and competing virgin materials: in
this  investigation the burden of proof is upon the railroads to  show that
any  rate structure is just, reasonable, and  non-discriminatory; the ICC
must issue orders requiring  the removal of  any unreasonable or
unjustly discriminatory rate; EPA is authorized to participate as a party
in such an investigation. The mandated ICC investigation is under way.
The draft Environmental Impact Statement of the ICC staff dismisses
as insignificant  the effects of freight rate changes on recycling.
Proposals for  further action should await conclusion of  the  current
investigation.

Procurement Specifications
  Government procurement specifications can reduce  the  demand for
recycled materials  by  discriminating against  them.  For example, the
  "COMMISSIONER WEINBERG: The logic of the refundable Swedish tax On
automobiles is so obvious and compelling that it is not enough to say merely that it
"merits further study." Adoption of a similar system in the United States should have
been recommended to facilitate recycling, to eliminate the eyesores represented by cars
abandoned on the streets and to spare  public authorities the cost tof,hauling them to
junkyards.

-------
Department of the Army recently cited its procurement specifications to
justify rejection  of  a recommendation by  its  Audit Agency  that it
purchase retreaded rather than new tires for its commercial  vehicles.42
GSA  (which  purchases $1.2 billion in  supplies annually) has already
made some progress in eliminating such discrimination. However,  DoD
(which purchases $32.6 billion in supplies annually) has indicated that it
would give low  priority  to anti-discrimination  arguments so long as
action  was  discretionary and not mandatory.43 There is some evidence
that the purchasing  specifications  of private industry also discriminate
unnecessarily against recycled materials.44
  The Resource  Conservation and Recovery Act of 1976  addresses the
problem of discriminatory procurement specifications. It  requires that
each agency  shall procure  items composed  of  the  highest practicable
percentage of recovered materials consistent with maintaining a satisfac-
tory level of competition.  The decision  not to procure such items  must
be  based on a determination  that such items  (1) are not reasonably
available, (2)  fail  to meet  performance  standards set forth in specifica-
tions based on guidelines to be issued by the Department of Commerce
through the National Bureau of Standards, or (3) are only available at
unreasonable  prices. Agencies  which generate heat  or  energy  from
fossil  fuels must, to the greatest practicable extent, use any  capability
for burning  recovered  material or  fuel  derived from  recovered
material. All  federal  agencies  must review and revise  procurement
specifications  to eliminate any exclusion  of recovered  materials  or
requirement that an item be manufactured from  virgin materials, and
to  require  use of reclaimed materials  to  the  greatest possible extent
without jeopardizing  the  intended end use of the item.  EPA  must
prepare guidelines for the use  of procuring agencies in complying with
the requirements of the section. The  Office of Procurement Policy is to
implement the policy  of  the Act  and report annually to Congress  on
actions taken.
  Under this Act, the  Department of Commerce (through the National
Bureau of Standards) must do more than develop specifications that
define the  ability of recycled  materials to  replace  virgin materials in
various industrial, commercial, and  governmental  uses.  It  must also
identify potential  markets for recycled  materials,  identify barriers  to
their  use, and encourage  the  development  of  new uses for recycled
materials. The  Department is also authorized to evaluate  the commer-
cial feasibility  of resource  recovery systems, publish  the results, and
develop a data base  to assist persons in  choosing such a system. Given
the Department's expressed lack of enthusiam  for this legislation, and
given the history of inattention to similar legislation (the Mining and
Minerals Policy  Act)  by  the  Department of the  Interior,  it is not
unreasonable to  fear that these provisions of the Act may  become a.
dead  letter. A specific dollar authorization for the Department  of
Commerce to carry  out these  duties, along with  continuing Congres-
sional  oversight, are  possible remedies.  The Government should
consider a variety of arrangements to disseminate information  to
industry. One  such promising arrangement is the Industrial Waste
Exchange of the St. Louis Regional Commerce and Growth Association,
which has just completed its first listing.44

                                                                169

-------
Institutional Barriers
  Institutional barriers prevent  increased  recycling  of municipal  solid
wastes.  The solid waste of a single metropolitan area  is often handled
by a number of jurisdictions with  conflicting interests. Many  cities lack
the power to contract for long-term delivery of waste;  such contracts
are often a precondition to private investment in recycling. Even where
cities do have the  necessary legal  authority and where  they  face
increasing costs for the disposal  of waste (especially in the Northeast),
they miss opportunities to recycle  waste because of the inertia of  their
solid waste management bureaucracies.*
  Widespread awareness  of opportunities  for resource recovery is the
first step  toward  overcoming \bureaucratic inertia and  institutional
barriers in this field. The ResouVce Conservation and  Recovery Act of
1976 is a promising  beginning. The Act  directs  EPA to provide
financial assistance and technical  assistance (through teams of experts in
finance, marketing,  technology,  and  law)  to the States in developing
and carrying  out plans for solid waste disposal and resource recovery
that will identify sources and markets. In order to qualify for assistance,
a State  plan must identify appropriate regional organizations authorized
to deal with  common solid  waste disposal and  resource  recovery
problems.  The plan also must remove  provisions prohibiting any  local
governments  from entering into  long-term  contracts to  supply  solid
waste to resource recovery facilities.

  The  Nation's supply of materials  will be used  most efficiently  when
decisions about the  use of materials are based  upon  their true  costs.
Although  the  recycling of waste material has often been  treated  as a
good per se, the Commission believes that the principle of determining
use by true costs applies just as fully to the resources contained in waste
material as it does to  the resources contained in virgin material.  The
Congress has  already  taken a number of commendable  steps in the
direction of implementing this principle. The Commission  urges that it
continue in this direction.

                             REFERENCES

 1 National Commission on Materials  Policy, Final Report 4D-8 (1973), and Cosman,
  "Studies of Recycling Problems in Selected Industries," in Commission Document,
  Additional Background Studies.
  *For example, it costs Washington, D, C. $15 per ton to dispose of its municipal
solid waste after collection. The city had an opportunity to sell collected waste to the
Potomac Electric Power Company, where it would have been burned as fuel on a pilot
plant scale and  its energy value recovered.  The city missed this opportunity in large
part because no one was willing to contend with bureaucratic obstacles to the
proposal; the city is now attempting to negotiate  a larger regional  energy recovery
agreement with PEPCO. "Interviews,  Dr. James G.  Abert, National Center for
Resource Recovery, Inc.; J.  Robert Holloway, Resource  Recovery Division,  Office of
Solid Waste Management Programs, Environmental Protection Agency.  For a more
general assessment of bureaucratic inertia in the solid waste field, see the address of
Dr. E. S. Savas in House Committee on Interstate and Foreign Commerce, Symposium
on Resource Conservation and Recovery, Comm. Print, 94th Cong., 2d Sess., 9-12 (1976).
170

-------
 2 Kirby and  Prokopovitsh, "Technological  Insurance  Against Shortages in Minerals
   and Metals," 191 Science 719 (February 20, 1976).
 " EPA, Third Report to Congress: Resource Recovery and Waste Reduction  10 (1975).
 4 See Cosman, op. cit.
 '' House Committee on  Foreign and Interstate  Commerce, Materials Relating to the
   Resource Consen>ation and Recovery Act of 1976,  94th Congress, 2d Session, Comm.
   Print 64 (1976).
 " 41 Fed. Reg. 2362 (January  15, 1976)
 7 See National Environment  Policy Act of 1969,  Pub.  Law 91-190 (January 1, 1970),
   42 USC §§ 4341  et seq.; Mining and Minerals Policy Act of 1970, Pub. Law 91-631
   (December 31, 1970),  30 USC §219;  Solid Waste Disposal  Act, as amended by
   Resource Recovery  Act of  1970,  Pub.  Law 89-272  (October  20,  1965), Pub. Law
   91-312  (October 16, 1970), 42 USC §§3251 et seq.; Federal Nonnuclear Energy
   and Development Act  of 1974,  Pub.  Law  93-577 (December 31, 1974), 42  USC
   §§ 5905-5906.
 " House Committee on Government Operation, Report No. 94-1319, 94th Congress,
   2d  Session 12 (1976).  See also  Blum, "Tapping  Resources in  Municipal Solid
   Waste,"  191 Science  674 (February  20, 1976), and Spendlove, Recycling Trend.': in the
   United States: A Revim* 20 (Bureau of Mines  Information Circular/1976).
 11 See Statement by Talbot  Page  in Hearings,  U.S. Senate Committee  on Public
   Works, Panel on  Materials  Policy, 94th Congress, 2d Sess., 6 (May 20, 1976) (cited
   hereafter as Hearing), and  Statement of  Richard B. Scudder  in House Committee
   on  Interstate  and  Foreign Commerce,  Symposium on Resource Conservation and
   Recovery, Comm. Print,  94th Cong., 2d Sess. 83 (1976).
 111 Baer, Johnson  and Morrow, Analysis of  Federally Funded Demonstration  Projects,
    Experimental Technology  Incentives  Program, U.S.  Department of Commerce,
    National Bureau of Standards, Vol. 1, iv-v  (April 1976).
 " House Committee on  Interstate and Foreign  Commerce, Materials Relating to the
   Resource Conservation and Recovery Act of  1976, 94th Congress, 2d Sess., Comm. Print
   70-71 (1976);  House Committee on Government Operations,  Report No. 94-1319,
   94th Congress, 2d Sess. 12 (1976).
 12 House Committee on  Government Operations, Report No.  94—1319, 94th Con-
   gress, 2d Sess.  6  (1976).
 13 U.S. Treasury Department, Tax Reform Studies  and Proposals, House Committee on
   Ways  and  Means and  U.S. Senate Committee on Finance, 91st  Congress, 1st
   Session, Comm.  Print  99-100 (1969) (cited  hereafter as Treasury Tax Reform
   Studies).
 14 See, e.g.,  Miller, "Percentage Depletion  and  the Level of Domestic Mineral
   Production" 15 Natural Resources].  248(1975).
 15 Interview,  Richard Johnson, Federal Trade  Commission;  also Cosman,  "The
   Threat of an Iron Ore  Cartel" (unpublished).
 16 See Booz-Allen and Hamilton, An  Evaluation o] the Impact of Discriminatory Taxation
   on the Use q/ Primary and Secondary Raw Material, (1975), and Environmental Law
   Institute, Federal Tax  Policy and Depletahle Resources:  Impacts and Alternatives for
   Recycling and Conservation (Draft,  1976).
 17 See, e.g., Charles River Associates, Inc.  "A Study  of the Ferrous Scrap Market
   During the Shortage Period of 1973-1974" in National Commission Supplies and
   Shortages, The Commodities Shortages of 1973-74: Case Studies.
 18 Miller, op.cit.  243-245.  See also Mancke, The  Failure of U.S. Energy Policy 85-87
   (1974).
 111 See Federal Trade  Commission, Quarterly Financial  Reports for Manufacturing,
   Mining and Trade Corporations, 1973-1976.  FTC reported figures for the lumber
   industry only  1972-1974, and for the mining industry 1974-1976.
211  J. Allen Overton, President, American Mining Congress,  letter to Dr. Eads,  with
   enclosures, August 20, 1976;  Simon  D. Strauss,  Executive  Vice  President,
   ASARCO, Inc., letter to Dr. Eads, October 5, 1976.
21  121 Cong.  Record H.I  163,  1187-1189 (February  27,  1975),  S.4233 (March  18,
   1975).
22  Simon D.  Strauss, Executive Vice President, ASARCO, Inc., letter  to  Dr.  Eads,
   October5,  1976.
23  Budget of the United States Government,  Fiscal Year 1977, Special Analysis  F,  123;
   interview, Cynthia Wallace,  Office of Tax  Analysis, Treasury Department.

                                                                            171

-------
24  Treasury Tax Reform Studies 428.
25  Ibid.
2li  Budget of the United States Government, Fiscal Year 1977, Special Analysis F,  123.
27  Treasury Tax Reform Studies, 435-438.
28  Arthur D.  Little, Inc., Analysis of Demand and Supply for Secondary Fiber in the U.S.
   Paper and Paperboard Industry IV-7 (1975).
29  Treasury Tax Reform Studies 434-435.
311  American Paper Institute, Statistics of Paper and Paperboard.
31  Arthur D. Little, Inc., op. at. 111-49.
32  See, Greenfield "The National  Forest Service and the Forest and Rangetand Renewable
   Resources Planning Act oyf 1974"  15 Natural Resources J, 605-606 (1975).
33  U.S. Senate Committee on Finance, Report No. 94-938, 94th Congress, 2d Session
   578(1976).
34  122 Cong. Record S.I 1073 (June 30, 1976).
35  See statements of William J. Baumol and Leonard Lee Lane, Hearing.
3li  Research Triangle Institute, An Evaluation of the Effectiveness and Costs of Regulatory
   and Fiscal Policy Instruments on Product Packaging,  Environmental Protection Agency
   (March 1974).
37  Statement of Sheldon Meyers, Hearing.
38  Gudger and Walters "Beverage Container Regulation"  5 Ecology L.Q. 265  (1976).
3!<  U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Domestic Commerce Staff Study, The
   Impacts of National Beverage Container Legislation  (October  1975); FEA, Energy and
   Economic Impacts of Mandatory  Deposits: Executive Summary (Sept. 1976); EPA,  Third
   Report to Congress: Resource Recovery and Waste Reduction, 29-30 (1975).
411  See EPA, Second Report  to Congress: Resource Recovery  and  Source Reduction  19—24
   (1974).
41  Resources Planning  Institute,  Raw Materials  Transportation  Costs and Their Influence
   on the Use of Wastepaper and Scrap Iron and Steel,  Environmental Protection Agency
   (April 1974).
42  General Accounting Office,  Report  to the Congress:  Policies  and Programs  Being
   Developed to Expand  Procurement oj Products Containing Recycled  Materials  12 (May  18,
   1976).
43  Ibid. 1,22-23.
44  Interview, Henri-Claude  Bailly, Resource Planning Associates, Inc.
45  7 Solid Waste Report  76 (May 10, 1976).
                                                                       SW-601
172

-------