Final Report
April 1976
RESEARCH TO ANTICIPATE ENVIRONMENTAL

IMPACTS OF CHANGING RESOURCE  USAGE



Symposium Proceedings




Prepared for:

OFFICE OF RESEARCH AND DEVELOPMENT
U.S. ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY
WASHINGTON, D.C. 20460
STANFORD RESEARCH INSTITUTE
Menlo Park, California  94025 • U.S.A.

-------
                                     EPA Review  Notice

   This  report has been reviewed by the Environmental Protection Agency and approved for pub-
lication.  Approval does not signify that the  contents necessarily reflect the views and policies of
the Environmental Protection Agency,  nor  does  mention of trade names or commercial products
constitute endorsement or recommendation for use.

-------
       STANFORD RESEARCH INSTITUTE
       Menlo Park, California 94025 • U.S.A
Final Report
April 1976
RESEARCH TO ANTICIPATE ENVIRONMENTAL
IMPACTS OF CHANGING RESOURCE  USAGE
Symposium Proceedings
STANFORD RESEARCH INSTITUTE
333 RAVENSWOOD AVENUE
MENLO PARK, CA. 94025
Edited by: KENDALL D. MOLL
Prepared for:

DR. JAMES C. HIBBS
OFFICE OF RESEARCH AND DEVELOPMENT
U.S. ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY
WASHINGTON, D.C.  20460

-------

-------
                                 PREFACE








      Inspiration for holding the Symposium which is reported in this



Proceedings arose from concern within EPA about the decreasing availabil-



ity of many natural resources, the impacts of changes in resource avail-



ability on environmental issues, and consequent needs for research by EPA.



Because the subject has many facets and is not uniquely structured within



EPA's or any other federal agency's existing research program, the spon-



sors wanted to obtain a wide spectrum of ideas from experts in government,



industry, academia, research, and public interest groups.  The resulting



symposium was held August 27 and 28, 1975, at Stanford Research Institute



in Menlo Park, California.





     A program representing a variety of disciplines was arranged with



papers presented by leading authorities on the subject of natural re-



sources and the environment, from various professional disciplines.   The



formal program consisted of a keynote and three background papers, five



viewpoint papers, and five reviewer responses.  All of these papers,



together with Introduction and Conclusions sections, are included in



this Proceedings.





     Meeting invitations were also extended to a select audience with



varied backgrounds, who were expected to participate in general discus-



sions and specialized workshops.  A list of the participants and attendees



is attached at the back of this Proceedings.





     Special appreciation is due Drs. James Hibbs and Harold Kibbee of




EPA, who guided the conceptualization and organization of the symposium.



Helpful comments on the Proceedings draft were obtained from Mr. E.  S.



Allen of Cyprus Mines Corporation,  Mr.  Michael Rothenberg of the San



Francisco Bay Area Air Pollution Control District,  and Dr. Richard A.



Schmidt of the Electric Power Research Institute.





                                   iii

-------
                                CONTENTS
PREFACE	   iii

INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY   	     1
   Willis W. Harman, Program Chairman, SRI

                           BACKGROUND ISSUES

KEYNOTE:  ACCOMMODATING THE NEW REALITIES 	    23
  William D. Ruckelshaus, Attorney and First Administrator of EPA

RESOURCE CHANGES, CONCEPTUAL DEVELOPMENT, AND RESEARCH NEEDS  ...    35
  John McHale, Director, Center for Integrative Studies
  State University of New York

THE EMERGING SITUATION FOR RESOURCES—AN EXTRAPOLATIVE VIEW ....    53
  Theodore J. Gordon, The Futures Group

RESOURCES, INDUSTRY, AND THE ENVIRONMENT  	    77
  Maurice R. Eastin, Special Assistant to the Administrator, EPA

                    RESEARCH NEEDS—FIRST VIEWPOINT

AN AGENDA FOR RESEARCH	    89
  Lynton K. Caldwell, Professor of Public and Environmental Affairs
  University of Indiana

REVIEW OF THE PAPER BY L. K. CALDWELL	   Ill
  Stanley A. Cain, Professor of Environmental Studies
  University of California, Santa Cruz

                     RESEARCH NEEDS—SECOND VIEWPOINT

AN INTERDISCIPLINARY APPROACH TO RESEARCH 	   121
  Robert C. North, Director, Institute of Political Studies
  Stanford University

REVIEW OF THE PAPER BY R. C. NORTH	   147
  Earl 0. Heady,  Director,  Center for Agricultural and Rural
   Development
  Iowa State University
                                    v

-------
                               CONTENTS

                    RESEARCH NEEDS—THIRD VIEWPOINT

RESEARCH IN AN ACCELERATING HUMAN ENVIRONMENT 	      167
  Ralph C. d'Arge, Professor of Economics, University of Wyoming

REVIEW OF THE PAPER BY R. C. d'ARGE	      187
  William E. Cooper, Professor of Zoology, Michigan State
  University

                    RESEARCH NEEDS—FOURTH VIEWPOINT

RESEARCH FOR REGULATORS  	      195
  George M. Woodwell, Director,  The Ecosystems Center
  Marine Biological Laboratory,  Woods Hole, Massachusetts

REVIEW OF THE PAPER BY G. M. WOODWELL	      205
  Sidney R. Galler, Deputy Assistant
  Secretary for Environmental Affairs, U.S. Dept.  of Commerce

                    RESEARCH NEEDS--FIFTH VIEWPOINT

SCARCITY, GEOPOLITICS, AND RESOURCE MANAGEMENT  	      211
  John Zierold, Legislative Advocate,  The Sierra Club

REVIEW OF THE PAPER BY J. ZIEROLD	      219
  Frank Sebastian, Senior Vice President, Envirotech Corporation

CONCLUSIONS	      241
  Kendall D. Moll, Proceedings Editor, SRI

APPENDIX:  SYMPOSIUM PARTICIPANTS AND ATTENDEES 	      259
                                   vi

-------
                       INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY

                      Willis W. Harman, Director
             Center for the Study of Social Policy, SRI
     Congress has stated a national policy to "restore and enhance the

quality" of  the environment as it affects all aspects of human well-being.

This policy  is developing in a context of uncertain but surely soaring

demands on resources of all sorts.  The conflicts and dilemmas of this

situation, and the needs for research to reduce uncertainties and re-

solve problems, form the focus of attention of the papers and discussion

that made up this symposium.

     The 13  contributors were all requested to address the same two

questions—namely:


     •  What factors may change patterns of resource usage in the
        future, and how?

     •  What research needs and priorities do these changes suggest,
        to improve the nation's ability to anticipate future environ-
        mental consequences?

The contributors were deliberately chosen to approach these questions

from widely diverse points of view.   The intent—and in this respect  the

symposium was especially successful—was to avoid unproductive adversary

confrontation and to engage in mutual exploration of the issues,  taking

full advantage of the enhancement contributed to a diversity of percep-

tions.   A number of participants  remarked on the need for mutual respect

in resolving the wide range of viewpoints.

-------
A Central Theme





     In spite of the wide spread of viewpoints, one theme turned out to



be omnipresent.  It was emphasized in different ways by various speakers




and in comments by audience participants, but never forgotten and never




contradicted.  That was the affirmation that a fragmented view of re-




source usage, economic development, and environmental problems can no




longer be considered adequate, and a total-system interdisciplinary ap-




proach is essential.  Often heard as a pious wish, this imperative was




expressed here as a basis for prompt action.





     In the  form of a crucial question, this central concern surfaced




again and again throughout the symposium.  Is extrapolation of present




resource consumption trends, even with all environmental protection



measures now contemplated, compatible with human well-being in funda-



mental respects—psychospiritual as well as material needs, wholeness




and mental health as well as physical health?  Or will it be necessary




to move very far and very fast in the direction of closed,  ecologically




sound industrial processes and resource-frugal lifestyles,  with revisions



in the economic structure as necessary to accommodate?





     The impetus for this question comes from the environmental implica-



tions of exponentially increasing world demand for physical resources




coupled with rapidly growing U.S. dependence on external sources (partly




a consequence of environmental controls).  But it comes equally from what




one speaker  called "the explosive growth in our actual and  potential




capacities to intervene in the larger environmental  processes."  "The




scale of our human systems begins to approach magnitudes which can affect



larger areas and relationships in the biosphere."





     A major implication of the question is that important  as environ-




mentally protective technology development may be,  it is not enough.   The




crisis we face—and most agreed it is a genuine crisis — is  an institutional

-------
 crisis.  The  most perplexing problems center around needs for institu-




 tional  revisions.





      Discussion of  the central theme tended to focus on three major con-



 cerns for  the future:   (a) forces opposing resource frugality, (b) forces



 opposing environmental protection measures, and (c) difficulties of plan-



 ning  for technological change.  Together these concerns generate a ma-



 jority  of  the high-priority research needs brought out in the symposium.






 Forces  Opposing Resource Frugality





      Obviously the  environmental impact of resource usage could be les-



 sened if the  use were reduced.  Yet the demands of the economy seem to



 actively oppose environmentally and ecologically sound developments in a



 number  of  ways.  Both from the standpoint of historical data and from a



 logical basis (since goods and services tend to use resources),  there is



 a  strong correlation between economic product and resource demand.  Any



 move  toward resource frugality that cuts into economic product will be



 opposed by forces within the economy, since its internal logic as well



 as  the  pressures of continuing world population growth requires con-



 tinuing increases in production.





      Economic forces and what has passed as good business practice urge



 consumers  to  replace their present durable goods with new ones—better



 or  just different.  Politically motivated taxation, subsidy, or price



 control schemes may force inefficient production patterns.   Both are




 in  opposition  to the environmentally sound concept of designing for



 durability and ease of repair.   Economic reasoning dictates using the



 cheapest source for materials;  this may conflict with the principle of



designing and planning for the total life cycle of materials.   Economi-



 cally efficient management would opt for the cheapest acceptable means



of waste disposal;  ecologically good management involves waste processing



to produce usable by-products.   Efficient management uses the most

-------
cost-effective production processes; ecological whole-system management

aims at closed industrial processes that minimize waste disposal demands

on the environment.

     Efficient resource production uses the cheapest methods legally

permissible under existing environmental protection legislation; eco-

logically sound resource utilization uses the methods that do least

violence to the local environment and to the total life-support system

of the planet.  Conventional business wisdom argues that business should

be as free as possible from governmental intervention,  and antitrust

interpretations in the courts tend to inhibit collaboration among corpo-

rations for any purpose.  Yet whole-system considerations indicate that

closed industrial processes can come about only if business organizations

and governmental agencies can interact very closely together.

     The dominance of economic incentives over other whole-system consid-

erations is clearly central to many of the most serious environmental

problems.  To repeat--"the crises are not in energy,  in technology,  in

the environment; they are all institutional crises."  That is they are

the results of specific values, attitudes, and institutional arrangements

for using these elements of the system.


Forces Opposing Environmental Protection Measures

     Some characteristics of the future seem ineluctable;  however,  much

choice may be left for other characteristics.   General  trends of recent

decades will continue into the future in a number of  environmentally
relevant respects:

     (1)   The present culture of developed nations and  the expectations
          of developing nations require ever-increasing resource usage.
          (For example, world production of mineral resources is doub-
          ling approximately every 7-8 years.)  This  tends to imply
          ever-increasing environmental impacts associated both with
          resource supply and with resource consumption.

-------
      (2)  Resources in general will be more expensive both because of
          their scarcity and because they will require higher levels
          oi technology input and greater capital investment.  This
          tends to imply greater environmental impacts associated with
          resource supply.
      (3)  Resources of many sorts (fossil fuels,  minerals, natural fresh
          water, arable land) will be increasingly harder to locate and
          extract or exploit, and will involve more environmental dis-
          location for their exploitation.

      (4)  There will be resource scarcities of various sorts, and in-
          creasing U.S. dependence on external sources; hence,  there
          will be tremendous pressures to develop indigenous U.S. and
          foreign resources, including those that have been uneconomical
          to develop at past prices and availabilities.  These pressures
          will tend to overwhelm environmental concerns.
      (5)  There will also be tremendous pressures on U.S.  agriculture to
          produce food for the world market, both to meet external food
          crises and to balance huge payments for foreign oil.   These
          pressures too will tend to override concern for the environment

      (6)  The world will become increasingly unstable over the world food
          issue.  There will be soaring demands for capital for large
          energy projects and urban reconstruction,  in a debt economy,
          hindering the financing of environmental protection equipment.
          All these will tend to increase the severity of environmental
          problems.

     On the other hand, sensitivity to environmental issues seems likely

to increase.  Disappointments over inability to meet previously set goals

will be one factor in this direction.  There will be more frequent and

more sudden impacts on planetary life-support systems because of increas-

ing magnitude of technological interventions and  the great complexity of

these ecological systems that precludes "complete modeling" and accurate

prediction.   Also,  the threat of irreversible global impacts may become

more apparent.

     Thus we seem headed for increasing confrontation between the indus-

trial system and those segments of human welfare  that depend on biotic

resources.  To  repeat—this creates an institutional crisis.

-------
Difficulties in Planning





     Besides the conflict between intrinsic economic incentives and eco-




logical motivations, and the anticipated extreme pressures because of




other societal problems, environmental restoration and enhancement faces




another kind of difficulty—the limitations on our ability to do long



range planning.  Various reasons for this were pointed out in the dis-




cussions—the compartmentalization of knowledge, the constrained time




attention span in both business and government, limited understanding of




how large and complex social systems really work,  the irrationality in




dealing with certain issues of the usual economic discounting of the




future, and the overall tendency of short-term problems to drive out



long range planning.





     If we have difficulties accomplishing long range planning,  it is



doubly true that we do not know how to do long-range whole-system plan-



ning.  And it is increasingly evident that we must learn.   Several of




the speakers went into more detail on what this implies.






Some Whole-System Aspects





     A convenient representation of resource-environment  relationships



in an industrialized society appears in Figure 1.   The planet provides




fundamental resources in what seemed until very recent years  essentially




unlimited quantity. Chief among these are surface  area, air,  water,  top-




soil, solar energy, biota, and subsurface concentrations.   The so-called



primary industries  (agriculture, forestry, fishing,  extractive industry,



and in earlier years hunting and trapping) deal with the  conversion of




these into derived resources (basic foodstuffs, natural fibers,  minerals



fossil fuels, saw logs).  Some of this is used directly by consumers.




However,  as the degree of industrialization increases,  a  larger  and larger



fraction of the derived resources is used by secondary and tertiary

-------
              ATTITUDES,  VALUES
            SOCIAL SYSTEM PROCESS
                 ASSUMPTIONS
                                   ENVIRONMENT
                                   AFFECTED BYx
                                                                                                1  TECHNOLOGY/CONSUMPTION
                                                                                                          PATTERNS
 RECYCLED
RESOURCES
DERIVED RESOURCES
  Basic Foodstuffs
  Natural Fibers
  Minerals
  Fossil Fuels
  Saw  Logs
                                                                   SECONDARY, TERTIARY, INDUSTRIES
(used for structure, fuel,
  input for processing)
                                                                     AGRICULTURE
                                                                     FORESTRY
                                                                     FISHING
                                                                     EXTRACTIVE
      PRIMARY
     INDUSTRIES
                                          FUNDAMENTAL RESOURCES:
                                                                                                          CONSUMER
                                                                                                          PRODUCTS
Surface Area
Air
Water
Topsoil
Solar Energy
Biota
Subsurface Concentrations
                                FIGURE 1   RESOURCE - ENVIRONMENT RELATIONSHIPS

-------
industries (for structure, as fuel or energy,  and as input for process-
ing) to produce goods and services to be used  by consumers.

     Environmental impact comes from the use patterns of resources and
products of various types, from the production of derived resources by
primary industries, and from the technology associated with production
of consumer products by secondary and tertiary industries.  People's
attitudes, values, and embedded assumptions affect the overall system
characteristics.  This, in simplified form, is the system involved in
whole-system change.

     Figure 2 is an attempt to represent in matrix form what was earlier
termed the central theme of the symposium.   There are a number of major
problem areas in society that are recognized as being to a greater or
lesser extent interrelated—problems of the physical and social environ-
ment, problems relating to food supply and  distribution, to energy,  to
matters of income and power distribution,  to resource depletion, and so
on.  Often these are dealt with as though they were separately resolvable
by technological and legal approaches (e.g., S0_ pollution abatement
                                               
-------
PROBLEMS
PERCEIVED
AS RESOLVABLE:
By Technological
and Legal Approaches
By Management
and Incentives
Approaches
Only By
Whole-System
Change
INTERRELATED PROBLEM AREAS
PHYSICAL
ENVIRONMENT
e.g.
Stack Gas
Scrubbers,
Air Pollution
Regulations
e.g.
Effluent
Taxes,
Land Use
Policies
SOCIAL
ENVIRONMENT
e.g.
Desegregation
Regulations,
Street Lighting
for Safe Streets
e.g.
Social
Programs
to Reduce
Crime
FOOD
e.g.
Green
Revolution
e.g.
Farm
Subsidies
ENERGY
e.g.
Breeder
Reactors,
Higher
Efficiency
Engines
e.g.
Energy Tax
DISTRIBUTION,
EQUITY
e.g.
Direct Aid to
Less Developed
Countries
e.g.
Industrialization
Assistance to
Less Developed
Countries
RESOURCE
DEPLETION
e.g.
Law to Prohibit
Throwaway
Containers
e.g.
Economic
Incentives
to Reclaim
Materials



e.g. Modifying Fundamental Characteristics
of the Industrial Production System;
Redistributing Population and Industry
to Reduce Transportation Needs
FIGURE 2   CONTRASTING PROBLEM PERCEPTIONS

-------
biotic patterns.  Examples are integrated industrial processes and urban

sewage systems that return organic waste to the land.

     In this systemic view of societal problems a number of intermediate

objectives could be set to reduce environmental impact through:

     •   Selection among alternative materials, processes, and products
         on the basis of low environmental impact as well as economic
         cost

     •  Changing extraction processes

     •  Changing transportation needs

     •  Changing resource processing

     •  Changing materials usage in fabricating and packaging

     •  Improving durability and repalrability of products

     •  Increasing resource reclamability.

To attain these intermediate objectives would require in most cases a

combination of a strong environmental ethic and altered incentive struc-

tures, since desirable changes from an environmental standpoint would

not necessarily be those that would increase return on investment or

market share.

     Longer range objectives—extending over more than a decade—are

even more difficult to achieve through planned intervention.  Examples

would be adjusting economic and other incentives to promote redistribu-

tion of population and industry, and to foster land use planning to
reduce transportation needs.  Another example might involve

de-industrializing food production to reduce agricultural energy de-

mand, transportation, packaging, and processing energy.  Research needs

for long range programs are great, since little is known about what spe-

cific system changes would be desirable, and how they might be brought

about.  Such needs can best be met by research programs that are indi-

vidually low-cost and high-risk (of significant results)  in contrast to

the high-cost low-risk research programs that are normally supported.

                                   10

-------
Bases for Selecting High-Priority Research

     From the various symposium discussions, as well as the arguments
above, emerged a number of proposed high priority research areas.  The

most important of these are:

     •  Research on emergent critical problems, especially those involv-
        ing potentially global and irreversible impacts
     •  Research to improve ability to anticipate critical problems
     •  Research to resolve critical uncertainties of a substantive
        nature
     •  Research to resolve critical uncertainties of an interpretive
        nature (e.g., whether the society is entering a period of rela-
        tively fundamental transformations)
     •  Monitoring areas of critical uncertainty.
Guide  to  Individual Papers

     The  prepared papers that constitute the central framework of the
symposium include (1) the keynote and three background papers, (2)  five
papers addressing the two theme questions from diverse points of view,
and  (3) five responses to those papers from five additional points  of
view.

     An Administrator's Viewpoint.  William Ruckelshaus,  first Adminis-
trator of the EPA provided some remarks from his vantage point.  He re-
minded the symposium participants that the pioneers of EPA took consid-
erable satisfaction in having created the Agency to attack in a coordi-
nated way the interrelated problems of air and water pollution, pesti-
cides, solid-waste,  and land use.  Even so,  they later found that envi-
ronmental problems cannot be separated from the whole social fabric.
The problem is less one of advancing the technology than of understand-

ing what costs should be accepted for what benefits.  The new realities

of changing resource usage require new patterns of coordination—EPA,

ERDA, and FEA working together on energy conservation, the recession

                                   11

-------
forcing attention to the economic impacts of environmental regulations,




EPA and Agriculture working together on low environmental impact agri-



cultural methods, and so on.   Equally, they require new abilities to



continually look into the future, to anticipate and accommodate to future




threats to environmental goals.





     Background Papers.   The first background paper, by John McHale,




stresses the institutional nature of the resource crises, mentioned




earlier.  The very concept of a  resource grows out of the institutions




of the society and their perceived needs.  Industrialized society is



creating an explosive growth in  resource needs, environmental impacts,




and capacities to intervene in the planet's life-support processes.  If




industrial growth seems to lead  toward "neo-Malthusian" hypotheses of




inevitable catastrophe,  it is because of an implicit assumption that the




basic institutional characteristics will remain unchanged.  With a guided




transformation of the industrial world's institutions,  it is possible to




conceive of accommodating more balanced growth and high technological




development with lowered resource demand and lowered environmental im-



pact.  But this view emphasizes  changes in perceptual and conceptual




"worldviews" which accompany, and often precede,  significant social,



economic, and political change.   Resource usage patterns and environmen-




tal impacts are inherent in a particular worldview,  and will change fun-



damentally only as that worldview changes.   We need "to recognize that




the environment is not only modified by physical  actions, but by our



ideas, beliefs, and value systems. .  .and the ways in which they operate



to influence policies and environmental decisions even more than do ma-



terial techniques."





     Ted Gordon's background paper has a similar tone.   He notes the huge



increasing demand for resources  with the ineluctable conclusion that the



environment will be severely stressed in producing and disposing of the




demanded materials.  The conclusion is "irrefutable," that exponential






                                   12

-------
growth of world population and resource-depleting production must ulti-




mately end—the questions are when and how,  "Not very soon" is Gordon's



answer to when.  The question of how leads him to the conclusion that



the industrialized and industrializing worlds face an unprecedented cul-



tural and institutional crisis.  In spite of promising technologies, he



doubts that the necessary changes can occur fast enough to resolve the



contradiction between increasing resource demands and environmental con-



sequences.  Gordon predicts "chaos" and suggests additional technological



measures to buy time.





     The third background paper by Maurice Eastin focuses on the need



for a more system-oriented view of resource utilization.   The environ-



mental problem can never be satisfactorily resolved through fragmented



regulation of air, water, and earth impacts.  Yet dealing with all these



plus the planet's living and life-support systems in an integrated



fashion is out of reach.  Faced with the inability to deal with the



total life-and-environment system, yet with the fact that "we cannot



live with the economics of the end-of-the-pipe environmental point of



view," we need to look toward an intermediate target—more efficient



subsystem processes from the standpoints of resources, economics,  and



energy.  The basic processes of industrialized society (e.g., agricul-



ture and food, paper and pulp,  construction materials') need to be ap-



proached with a systems orientation, with an eye to converting waste



products to by-products and new products.  This is an approach toward



which EPA is evolving, moving from negative restrictive control to pos-



itive environmental synthesis.





     First Viewpoint.  Lynton Caldwell presented the first of the five  '



viewpoints.   He emphasized the need for an improved framework of knowl-



edge about the general and basic causes of our environmental predicament.



Lacking an adequate conceptual  framework, we lack the basis for guiding



research to  bring our general environmental situation under control;






                                   13

-------
attacking specific problems of environmental protection may invite others




equally unwelcome.





     One of the key points highlighted by Caldwell is the political, con-




ceptual, and psychological difficulty of dealing with the resource-



environment problem in the consumption phase rather than concentrating




efforts almost solely on the supply phase—that is, of seeking an im-



proved system rather than "making the present system work better."  With




regard to research priorities, Caldwell argues for "a structure or hier-



archy of environmental knowledge that would be larger than the operational




agenda of any agency, but which could provide orientation and perspective



for the research missions of organizations such as the EPA."  For an as-




sortment of political and cultural reasons this most-needed research is



very difficult for any government agency or even foundation to support.




We will probably have instead a much less systemic, more risk-averse,




problem focused, and ultimately less effective and more costly research



program.





     Stanley Cain argues only mildly with Caldwell in commenting on his




paper.  He further emphasizes the need, and the difficulty,  of a broader



scope for inquiry than can with propriety be mounted by a government




agency with legally restricted cognizance.   As Cain says, "the holistic



science of ecology is well and working."  We are coming to realize "the




intricate interconnections of life and environment."  Yet because of




compartmentalization of knowledge and of institutional responsibility,




it will be difficult to acquire the knowledge,  authority, and understand-



ing we require to resolve our environmental problems.   Although "it is




profitless to do research only on existing resource-use patterns," this




is predominantly what we will do.  We need to see our problems whole.



Yet the temptation instead is to find someone to blame.   The lesson we




have yet to learn is,  "when the causes are shared by everyone,  when the



system is at fault,  the victims are the culprits."






                                   14

-------
      Second Viewpoint.  Robert North's paper explores in more detail the



 implications of an  interdisciplinary systemic view.  Arguing that envi-



 ronmental  consequences come essentially from three variables—population,



 resources, and technology--he elaborates the need for research to model



 all of  these together, taking into account the complex pattern of social,



 economic,  and political changes on their interrelationships.  A large



 portion of North's  discussion goes to making the point that our accus-



 tomed ways of dealing with problems are ill adapted to problems that are



 systemic in character.  As he puts it, "a social system tends to draw



 our attention to  the very points at which an attempt to intervene will



 fail."  We tend to  look close to the symptoms of trouble for an apparent



 cause;  however, that cause is not the basic cause,  and thus the proposed



 remedy  turns out  to be ineffective or to produce "unintended consequences'



 or counterintuitive results."  Through lack of understanding of how the



 whole system operates, and through lack of an accepted goal structure,



 micro-decisions are made that sum to bad macro-decisions for the overall



 society.   This will be exacerbated as we move into  a period of intense



 competition for critical resources.  Thus the highest priority should be



 assigned research on system simulation, whole-system forecasting, and



 evaluation of alternative assumptions and alternative courses of action



 for the future.





      Earl Heady, in commenting on North's paper, expresses himself as



 more  optimistic that the difficulties of interdisciplinary research on



 total life-environment-society systems can indeed be surmounted.  He



 notes successes in interdisciplinary university research efforts, in



 large-scale modeling,  in evaluating tradeoffs and comparing the conse-



quences of alternative policies to substantiate his point.  He urges re-



search on incentive systems (e.g., taxes,  subsidies) for political im-



plementation of values (e.g.,  clear streams,  natural beauty) not expres-



sible in the marketplace (i.e.,  externalities), and to ameliorate the
                                   15

-------
problem of excessive discounting of the future.   Secondly,  he sees the
need for expanded research efforts on modeling complex social systems.
Finally, he urges altering EPA's research approach to a more positive
and long-term emphasis on developing technologies and resource that avoid
deleterious environmental consequences.
     Third Viewpoint.  At first  reading,  the paper by Ralph d'Arge may
seem to strike a different note.  He defines an emerging class of envi-
ronmental problems:   ones where  extremely long-term or irreversible im-
pacts might occur, where multinational and even global impacts are antic-
ipated, and where the set of outcomes is  at least partially unknown and
highly uncertain.  He points out that present guides to decision-making
do not adequately take into account possible long-term and  potentially
irreversible effects.  He notes  the limitations  of modeling when assess-
ing the range of plausible outcomes; "man will not (ever) understand in
detail the interweaving patterns and forces within his own  ecosystem
because he can never observe all the interdependencies.  And we have no
effective way of handling problems of the "global commons"  (e.g.,  the
oceans the stratosphere,  nuclear wastes).   d'Arge urges high research
priority for this class of problems, and  concentration of research funds
on the most impending of these.   This emphasis on control strategies for
a limited class of environmental problems seems  superficially distinct
from the emphasis on whole-system approaches advocated in so many of the
other papers.   However,  the difference turns out to be more apparent
than real, because when these "most urgent" problems are examined the
solutions appear to lie less in  technological advance than  in system
change.

     William Cooper agrees that  d'Arge identifies a set of  problems that
will be of increasing concern "as synthetic compounds are developed and
produced in a  frantic effort to  escape the ultimate constraints of mate-
rial limitations and/or the thermodynamic implications of dependence on

                                   16

-------
closed energetic systems."  The difficulty with controlling these prob-
lems using economic incentives, standards, regulations, and penalties,
is that the control system must be designed to perform almost flawlessly.
The alternative approach is system redesign to achieve satisfactory per-
formance and resilience assuming that there will be individual and in-
stitutional mistakes which no system of control will be able to prevent.
Again the prime need expressed is for a research program on overall sys-
tem control and design supported by experimental approaches to incremental
change.
     Fourth Viewpoint.  The paper by George Woodwell centers around the
confrontation between the industrial system with its emphasis on short-
term profits and those segments of human welfare that depend on biotic
resources, a confrontation that must become steadily more acute with
instances more common.  The alternative to the present situation is clear.
In a world with soaring population and soaring demands on resources,  the
basic pattern in use of the environment must become the closed system.
The basic principle is not pollution within limits, to be corrected.   It
is, rather an approach toward no pollution by designing cities,  indus-
tries, and agriculture to be as nearly as possible self-contained,  recir-
culating water- nutrients, metals, and wastes in ways that do not make
excessive demands on the "assimilative capacity" of the environment.
The central principle is the preservation of the earth's basic chemical
and biotic patterns, as written into the policy statement of the Water
Pollution Control Act Amendments of 1972.  The research needed to guide
the transition to closed systems would include, as examples (a)  a con-
tinuing analysis of the world's carbon budget to discern when dangerous
imbalances occur,  (b)  a program to discover the details of biotic impov-
erishment and how to recognize the earliest stages of it, and (c) a
vigorous program on the recirculation of water and nutrients in sewage.
                                  17

-------
     Sid Caller's comments on the Woodwell paper are mainly by way of




emphasis.  Agreeing with Woodwell's basic principle of "no pollution;



not pollution within limits" and with the urgency of attention to impacts




on the global carbon budget, Galler disagrees sharply on one point.  He




contradicts Woodwell's suggestion that the EPA should be given responsi-




bility for basic research to preserve "the earth's basic chemical and




biotic patterns."  Caller's argument is that this large and important




task requires resources and capabilities going far beyond those likely




to be, or appropriate, for a primarily regulatory agency, and that the




knowledge required for this task derives from a wide variety of basic



and applied research investigations that are appropriately carried out




in a diversity of existing agencies.





     Fifth Viewpoint.   John Zierold's paper concentrates on the energy




and world food crises, and the pressures these will bring on the environ-



ment.  Among the topics are environmental impacts of urban sprawl,  re-




source recovery from low-concentration sources,  resource processing and



transportation, preservation of prime agricultural lands, and preserva-




tion of green spaces within urban areas.  It is  typical of such problem




areas that the solution is only to a limited extent technological.   A



good part of the problem comes about because present economic incentives




tend to be inimical to environmental protection.   The point is made again,




as so many times throughout the symposium—research toward redesign of




the economic and industrial-agricultural system  seems central to long-



term resolution of environmental problems.





     The response to this paper by Frank Sebastian includes a detailed




report on progress in water reclamation, indicating both technological



progress and economic .viability of wastewater recovery.   The message is



clear—in emphasizing the needed systems research,  stressed so many times




through the symposium, do not overlook the technical progress on specific



ameliorative measures.





                                   18

-------
Summary of Research Priorities





     From these highlights of individual papers it is clear that certain



themes stood out, and yet that there was a great diversity of viewpoints.



As a brief summary of the research priorities identified,  we might pick




out the following six themes:





     1.  Environmental Systemic Interactions.  This need was identified



more strongly than any other.  The whole system includes not only physi-



cal environment and institutions but also social,  economic, and cultural



beliefs and values.  Modeling and research are needed toward understand-



ing interactions in the whole agricultural and industrial production



system, toward relatively closed, resource-frugal  subsystems, and toward



overall system incentives more compatible with preservation of the



earth's basic chemical and biotic systems.  A systems approach implies



far more attention to the consumption phase of resource use—to reducing



resource demands within the system, in contrast to present and projected



research which is heavily weighted toward the supply phase.  Since this



in turn implies changes in lifestyles and a more frugal culture, research



should involve public dialogue and education on central issues and pol-



icies .





     2.  Resource Usage Patterns.  Numerous intermediate objectives in-



volving subsystem modification were cited.  Among  them were reducing



environmental impact of extraction and processing, improving use-recycle



processes for materials, reducing energy use, reducing materials usage



in fabricating and packaging, and improving durability and repairability



of products.





     3.  Incentives for Controlling the Environment.  Present economic



incentives tend to conflict with environmental protection and enhance-



ment.   Short-term profit incentives and consumer fads mitigate against



product durability and repairability and heavily discount the future.
                                   19

-------
Economic growth imperatives make it difficult to cut back on energy and



materials use.   The long-term resolution of our environmental situation




may require major readjustment of this incentive system.





     4.  Critical. Ecological Problems.  Special attention needs to be




given to critical problems where very long-term impacts might occur,



global in nature, and where the set of outcomes is at least partially




unknown and highly uncertain.  These include the oceans,  the stratosphere,




CO  atmospheric centration, and nuclear waste.   An ongoing research pro-



gram, screening new materials and products and  monitoring both environ-




mental and social trends,  is required to anticipate critical problems.





     5.  Applied Research  and Technological Developments.   Not to be




overlooked in the emphasis on systemic problems are the specific research




and technological advances that can reduce or ameliorate  environmental




impacts.  Examples include low environmental impact technologies, re-




cycling and waste processing technologies, materials substitution, and




materials-conserving production and technology.





     6.  Environmental Monitoring and Assessment.   Observation of both




critical uncertainties and control programs should have high priority.




Some scenarios for the future implicitly assume that the  trends of the




future will be more or less the trends of the past, and that the problems



of the future do not differ in kind from the problems society has learned




to deal with by technological prowess and appropriate institutional inno-




vations.  Another group, hov/ever, assumes that  a combination of histori-




cal forces and physical limitations have brought society  to a point of



fundamental system transformation.  The "limits to growth" thesis is but




one form of this second argument, which says that the consequences of



advanced industrialization v/ill soon become so  intolerable that a major



restructuring of industrialized society may be  inevitable.  According to



this view, partial system  breakdowns accompanying this major societal




transformation will become evident during the next decade or so.  Because





                                    20

-------
uncertainty is so crucial in the accurate interpretation of societal



problems, it is imperative that careful monitoring be instituted  to



determine as early as possible which track the society is on.





     A more complete listing of recommended research areas,  coming out



of the symposium proceedings, will be found at the end of this  report.
                                   21

-------
             ACCOMMODATING THE NEW REALITIES

William D. Ruckelshaus, Attorney and First Administrator
          U.S. Environmental Protection Agency
                    Washington,  D.C.

-------
                    ACCOMMODATING THE NEW REALITIES



                        William D. Ruckelshaus








     I applaud the non-confrental approach of this conference.   I  have



concluded in the four and one-half years since EPA started,  contrary to



my every instinct as a lawyer and advocate, that in today's  climate con-



frontation, and the adversary system we use to make so many  environmental



decisions, are in the last analysis too often causing bad decisions.



These decisions, couched in terms of winners and losers by legislative,



administrative, and judicial declaration, are not focusing enough  on the



public interest, but instead handing "victory" to one of the adversaries.





     I applaud the SRI conference effort to avoid the endless and  pres-



ently unresolvable debate over what the future holds for man.   If  we take



as a starting point that we don't know what tomorrow will bring we can



focus on what is advisable for man--and not spend endless hours debating



what is inevitable.





     The Environmental Protection Agency came into existence only  four



and a half years ago.  It sometimes seems like four score and four years



because a number of startling events have taken place in the interceding



years.  (My transfer from EPA to the FBI was the one of the  more per-



sonally startling events.)   Perhaps for all of us the time seems so long



because our political/economic climate is so different from  that prevail-



ing at the start of the decade.





     The year 1970 saw the first Earth Day and an explosion  of public




awareness and concern about the environment.  As a people we came  to have



a better understanding of the biological, physical,  and chemical inter-



relationships of life on this planet;  and at the same time,  naively,  we





                                   25

-------
also came to believe that environmental problems could be separated out




and addressed by themselves.   Congress and state legislatures passed



some tough,  demanding laws.   The American people indicated at least pre-




liminarily that they were willing to bear the costs needed to clean up




the environment within the tight time frames set by their elected




representatives.





     An energy crunch featuring dramatically higher energy prices that




contributed to worldwide inflation in concert with recession have changed




the world economic and American societal conditions considerably.   Tight




public and private pocketbooks and the need to cope with unemployment




have replaced the era of deep pockets for worthwhile projects we knew




only a short time ago.  These changed conditions,  coupled with the ero-




sion of public confidence in  our institutions—both private and public--



that began in the late 1960s  and accelerated with Watergate,  create a



situation which many environmentalists feel poses a catastrophic threat




to their goals.  In response, some are attempting to stiffen or at least




hold the line of our present  environmental laws—rather than to accommo-



date the new realities.





     I don't believe that our energy and economic problems are the



harbinger of the end of environmental progress in this country,  nor do



I believe in reacting to these problems by increasing the inflexibility




of our approach to environmental problems as some unfortunately--in




Congress, executive agencies, and the environmental movement—are in-




clined to do.   I would rather discuss the positive aspects of our cur-



rent situation—and to put forth a perspective of the future I believe



we should adopt to guide us wisely through the years ahead.





     The great judge and scholar, Learned Hand,  once defined "justice"




as the  tolerable accommodation of the competing interests of society."




I think we can—and should—use the concept of accommodating competing
                                  26

-------
interests to guide our approach to societal problems such as environ-



mental degradation, where in total only limited resources are available



to meet virtually unlimited social demands.





     In the early days of EPA we took a certain amount of satisfaction



in the fact that we at last realized the problems of air and water



pollution, pesticides, solid-waste and land use are interrelated and



should not be addressed in isolation.  In fact we created EPA,  a new



government agency, to attack these problems in a coordinated way.   We



sought to imbue the Barry Commoner concept "that everything is  connected



to everything else" in our public and private consciousness.  But for



all of our environmental farsightedness, we were at the same time ex-



hibiting societal shortsightedness when we viewed the environment as



unrelated to other problems.





     It took long gasoline lines to bring us to the realization that  the



environment is not unrelated to other issues—and that the social fabric



is like a balloon—if you push in at one point, it will bulge out at



another.  We are coming to better understand that we have only  limited



economic and natural resources for which there are virtually unlimited



demands.  We are  coming  to see that we cannot solve problems incremen-



tally as if they were unrelated to other problems.





     When I was the Administrator of EPA, I had mixed emotions  about



trying to solve the air pollution problems of urban areas like  Los



Angeles.  It was clear that air pollution was really part of their



transportation problem, which was part of a larger problem of the qual-



ity of life they really wanted.  So our hopes for solving the air pol-



lution problem were too optimistic.  It turned out, in spite of the



mandate by Congress that air throughout the country would be pure by



June of 1975, that Los Angeles still has a major problem.  In fact one



of EPA's transportation control studies indicated that L.A.'s photo-




chemical oxygen standard could be met by removing 92 percent of the




                                  27

-------
automobiles from the highways.   In January of 1973 1  was ordered by the




District Court of Los Angeles to provide a transportation control plan




for Los Angeles or be held in contempt.   So I went to Los Angeles and




announced that 92 percent of their automobiles would  have to get off the




road.  I admit I made the announcement at the airport and immediately




flew out.





     There is one great lesson we should draw from our efforts  in the




1960s and early 1970s—that merely pouring out large  sums of money or




setting tough but unrealistic deadlines  for a single  problem will not




necessarily result in the public interest being served.   Not only is our




own society more interdependent than in  the past—so  is  the world.




Droughts in the farmlands of Russia,  and actions by tiny shiekdoms in




the Mideast, can and do significantly affect our own  cost of living and




economic wellbeing.





     I have the deep sense that the public in this country--in  a visceral




way--is more aware of the interrelationship of our societal problems in-




cluding energy and the economy and the environment than  is our  leader-




ship.  Particularly, it seems ahead I think of the Congress.   I was con-




vinced in 1970, when we started to implement the new  laws that  Congress




had passed, that while it was necessary  to move forcefully and  intelli-




gently and with as much vigor as possible,  there would come a time when




the public would recognize that the problem was less  one of advancing




the technology than it was of what costs should be expended for what




benefits.  Unfortunately, many of the debates that were  going on five




years ago are still going on today at the same level  of  confrontation.




Partly this is because of our inability  to take advantage of the lessons




learned and to explain these lessons to  the committees of Congress.  I




would blame this mainly on the Watergate affair,  in that the attention




of the public and the Congress was riveted for two years almost exclu-




sively on this problem.  Now that we have reached the time where






                                   28  ,

-------
environmental laws need to be changed, we again find ourselves in a much



more confrontational atmosphere.





     There  is a  real need to take a dispassionate look at how competing



social demands can be accommodated, and a need to abandon in many cases



the practice of  taking each problem to the point of confrontation.  Con-



frontations may  make great news stories—they encourage people to take



sides and to focus on who is acclaimed "the winner."  But if a problem



is viewed as the environment versus the economy or the environment versus



energy, with one or the other side winning, inevitably the public inter-



est will lose because almost by definition the public interest is an



accommodation.   A number of the major issues I had to wrestle with during



my tenure at EPA were depicted in the press as the "white hats" against



the "black  hats"—and score was kept of the number of supposed victories



by each.  It was difficult to get the message across to the press—and



through them to  the public—that the real question was not who "won" or



who "lost"—but  whether the action taken was in the public interest—



whether it was a wise decision.  It is discouraging to me that the media



emphasis is even now on whether a decision is "tough" or "weak" and not



on the essential question:  Is it wise?





     While not at the peak level of 1970-71, membership in major environ-



mental organizations is holding fairly steady.  And the polls show that



the public continues to consider the environment to be an important



issue.  These are good indications.  A Harris poll released in March



showed that the  American people ranked air and water pollution as the



nation's third and fourth greatest problems—second only to inflation



and unemployment.  At the same time I believe that the public understands



the need for reasonable accommodations with other pressing social prob-



lems,  and expects that they will be made.  How then are our major public



institutions—Congress and the federal agencies—responding to the public



will?





                                   29

-------
     In the early 1970s Congress reacted  to  public pressure and passed




a number of major environmental  laws that embodied lofty goals and set




stringent standards.   In my opinion, like too  many laws  adopted by Con-



gress,  the environmental laws were adopted in  isolation  from other issues




and were based on optimistic assumptions  as  to how much  progress could




be achieved in what time frame and what resources  the society should



commit  to making that progress.   Reflecting  Congressional dissatisfac-




tion with the past rate of progress, the  new laws  set out rigorous time



frames  for certain actions by both the public  and  private sectors that




would require massive expenditures of money.   But  they gave EPA and the




states  relatively little flexibility.





     EPA began to push its own bureaucracy,  the states,  municipalities




and industry in the directions and at the speeds dictated by Congress.



One of  the early actions was to  urge that utilities convert their boilers




to use  oil rather than coal to reduce the emission of sulfur oxides.   No




sooner  was this shift of resources underway  than our energy supply and




economic conditions forced a reappraisal,  and  another Federal Agency is



now ordering the switch from oil back to  coal.





     The measure of our institutions must be as much or  more in their




ability to respond and adopt to  changed conditions as in their ability




to design sound solutions for static problems.   On this  score we find



that Congress has not only put in place too  inflexible a structure for



addressing environmental problems (a structure that in part requires




economic commitments based on much rosier conditions), but the committees




responsible for environmental legislation are  still reluctant to legis-



late needed changes responsive to the new realities.   That is why I have




concluded that the public is far ahead of Congress in realizing that we



cannot  afford an unlimited blank check to clean up the air and water--




and that progress that can be made must be considered against the social



and economic costs that will be  entailed, the  resources  that'are





                                   30

-------
available, and the ways in which those limited resources can most effec-



tively be directed.





     At first EPA had a fairly free hand in the course of implementing



the Clean Air Act to de facto require the allocation of certain kinds of



energy resources, particularly of low sulfur fuels,  to certain areas of



the country and to certain uses.  But recently, Russel Train has been



more constrained because the competing social concerns have become much



more apparent.  Now EPA must work and accommodate its goals relating to



availability and best use of our energy resources with the Federal Energy



Administration and the Energy Research and Development Administration.



The environment is no longer the sole consideration.   Reconversion of



certain oil-fired boilers back to coal sharpened the conflict between



competing interests of the agencies--and ultimately  forced the required



accommodation.





     On the other various issues, the agency interests are similar to



each other, and coordination of resources and responsibilities is impor-



tant.  EPA's solid waste office and ERDA will be working together on the



development of solid waste as an energy source.  With more projects like



the Union Electric Plant in St. Louis where solid waste is burned to



generate electricity, we are on the way to turning a disposal problem



into a useful resource.





     Similarly I gather that EPA, ERDA, and FEA are  working together on



how best to increase public awareness of the need and means of energy



conservation.  While their overall missions differ,  in the energy con-



servation area,  their interests and the public interest coincide.  These



are among the hopeful signs I see--that EPA recognizes it must come to



grips with the new conditions and the new public mood.  Agencies by



necessity reflect public opinion—and they become more or less aggres-



sive depending on public attitudes.  This is not necessarily bad.  It's



the way a democracy is supposed to work.




                                   31

-------
     The economic downturn clearly has made EPA pay more attention to




the economic impact its regulations are having.  This was happening be-




fore I left.  Someone counted four times as many economists on our staff



as ecologists.   (That is not a statistic we normally published.)   In the




environmental area, like a number of other areas,  tight  economic  condi-




tions help the society become more efficient.





     The theme of this symposium,  "research needs  to anticipate environ-




mental impacts of changing resource uses," is  giving you many knowledg-




eable presentations on the problems that EPA should be addressing.   If



I could add one message, it would be for EPA and indeed  all Government




agencies to continually look into the future to see what factors  may



inhibit the achievement of their goals,  and to build in  mechanisms  to




anticipate and accommodate those problems.





     The emergence of the energy and economic  problem can be beneficial



if it aids us in organizing our legislative and administrative processes




to accommodate new realities into existing efforts  to solve problems—



and to better recognize the interdependence of our  world.





     We should not underestimate the challenge to  leadership that modern




problems present.   Environmental problems themselves are complicated




and, when you add problems like energy scarcity and economic downturn,




the equation is bound to produce answers that  are unclear and contro-



versial.  No one will be satisfied.





     In one sense what we need to restore confidence is  more Mayaguez




incidents.  Someone swiped our boat,  and we took it back.   What could be




clearer?  I think the clear-cut nature of that problem and its clear-cut




solution accounts for the overwhelmingly positive  response to the Ameri-



can people to that incident.





     But the new environmental realities are quite  different.  Someone



or a group of someones has quadrupled the price of  oil.   What do  we do





                                  32

-------
about it?  No one has a very good answer.   This kind of problem contri-



butes to the continued dissatisfaction and erosion of confidence in our



government.  Yet these are the President's daily problems.   We should



keep them in mind when we criticize leadership by him and other heads of



state.





     I don't believe we should view the new realities as a threat to



cleaning up the environment—but rather as a challenge to accommodating



a desirable social goal like clean air within the matrix of other social



problems.  If we lack the ability to adjust the pace with which we are



addressing a given problem, or if we cannot accommodate our ultimate goal



to a new consideration, we risk losing all our momentum toward solving



that problem.  Instead, we must be sure we are setting reasonable goals



so that our progress will give us the confidence to go on to the next



goal.





     When I became the Administrator of EPA I believed very strongly



that the challenge of the environment offered us an opportunity as a



society to restore some of our confidence  in our ability to deal success-



fully with a major complex problem.   I continue to believe that this



prospect is available to us in the environmental arena—despite high



energy costs, changing resource demands,  inflation and recession—if we



carefully accommodate our goals to the new realities.
                                  33

-------
RESOURCE CHANGES, CONCEPTUAL DEVELOPMENT,  AND RESEARCH  NEEDS

                     John McHale,  Ph.D.
          Director, Center for Integrative Studies
                School of Advanced Technology
         State University of New York at Binghamton

-------
       RESOURCE CHANGES, CONCEPTUAL DEVELOPMENT, AND RESEARCH NEEDS



                                John McHale








     Resource changes not only impact our social structure,  but also



cause changes in perceptual and conceptual "worldviews" which accompany,



and often precede, significant social, economic, and political change.



One might initially suggest that our concepts with regard to resources,



their impact on the environment, and usage of the term environment itself,



have all changed radically in the past few decades.





     Many of our principal resources were not even conceptually recog-



nized as such a relatively short time ago.  Aluminum was a scarce metallic



curiosity, radioactivity a laboratory phenomenon, and many of our key



metals were regarded as waste impurities in other ores.  In this fashion,



our range of useful resources is ultimately as we conceive it to be.  It



is dependent both on the state of our knowledge and the perception of our



needs.  These also change and interact with one another.





     With regard to environment, two critical aspects of change have be-



come dramatically visible:





     The first is the explosive growth in our actual and potential capac-



ities to intervene in the larger environmental processes.  This is evi-



dent in the increase in human population, the transformation of the earth



to human purposes, and in the range and amounts of energy and materials



exploited.  The scale of our human systems begins to approach magnitudes



which can affect larger areas and relationships in the biosphere.





     The second is the lag in conceptual grasp of this transformation and



in the understanding through which we may manage its changes more effec-



tively.   One shift that has taken place is that "nature" or "environment"




                                   37

-------
is no longer something to be conquered—but protected and conserved.  We




begin to recognize that human decisions not only determine environmental




conditions but most other aspects of the human condition.





     Attention has been focused primarily on the impacts of technology




on the physical environment.  More recent thinking indicates the prior




importance of "institutional" impacts; i.e. that the crises are not in



energy, in technology, in. food supply, ijn the environment, and so forth.




They are all institutional crises.  They are the results of specific



values, attitudes, and institutional arrangements through which these




activities are conducted.  Many of these economic,  political,  and other




policies have been expedient and practical in the short range.  It is




only now when their visibly dysfunctional effects have become  apparent




in the longer range that they emerge at crisis levels--but still with




least attention to their real causal origins.





     Given the nature of the crisis, many people have accepted,  somewhat



uncritically, a revised set of neo-Maithusian premises.   Human growth




within a finite earth system is viewed as leading almost inevitably to



catastrophe within the next half century.  Many recent proposals emanat-




ing from this viewpoint contain explicit, or implicit, abnegation of



continued technological and material growth,  which is viewed as the



major factor leading to critical imbalance.  Some advocate the return



to more frugal, and even more pastoral modes,  as ways of avoiding the



crisis.





     But while recognizing the need for more rational growth policies,




there is no necessary or essential connection between the development of




advanced technologies, the material improvement of living standards, and



deteioration of the natural environment.





     There is no absolute relation between high production and consump-




tion with high environmental impact.  Many of the richer countries in
                                  38

-------
the world have significantly "cleaner" living environs than the poorer.



The severe problems of local and worldwide pollution are due to lack of



foresight, inadequate planning, and mismanagement.  They are institu-



tional and regulatory in origin rather than absolutes.





     There is, again, no direct linkage between population growth and



high environmental pressure.  Many of the richer countries with high pop-



ulation densities have significantly less impacted environments than the



poorer.  In terms of population growth rates, most future growth will be



in the lesser developed countries whose material resource usage is still



relatively small—whereas most anxiety is felt in the developed countries



whose populations are stabilizing and whose resource consumption could,



and in some cases is, leveling off.  Where environmental impact is still



high in the latter it is due to wasteful resource management,  planned



obsolescence of products, and overstimulation of demand, among other



factors.





     As we shall discuss, more balanced growth with less resource demand



and high technological development may be accommodated with low environ-



mental impact.





     There are a set of more specific points which I have been asked to



touch upon.  One set relates to resource availability, new technologies



and life style changes, and how these may affect EPA policies.  The re-



source availability question is directly related to technological devel-



opment .





     Energy is the most obvious issue here and yet the most clouded one.



We have reiterated emphasis on the energy crisis but more clearly this



is not an energy but an oil crisis—and then not a crisis in terms of



actual shortage but in terms of price and availability.  It is a crisis



that has been allowed to occur in terms of a preferred fuel use for con-



venience,  profitability,  and expediency.
                                   39

-------
     In terms of resource supply,  the real problem may be a return to




oil surplus due to extended exploration and the use of oil sands and



shale—thus encouraging more profligate use of a potentially more valu-




able source of petro-chemicals,  medicinals, plastics,  and even new food




sources, than of a material to be wantonly burnt up.





     What are the prospects for adequate energy supply in the face of




increased demand?





     The conventional mode is to treat this in terms of reserve capacity




against current and extrapolated rates of consumption.   For oil and nat-



ural gas, these are conservatively estimated to vary from 30 to 50 years,




for coal upwards by magnitudes of 200 to 500 years.   No one knows exactly




what reserves exist, and figures are constantly revised upwards.   Rates




of consumption have about the same confidence level as indicators.





     Nuclear fission power obviously extends this capacity but has greater




environmental hazards in terms of operation and radioactive waste dis-



posal .





     How does this fit with longer range EPA policy?  Leaving aside the




obvious encouragement of alternative energy sources, one key factor in



short and long-term adequacy is efficiency of energy use.   Wasteful




energy uses are not only uneconomical but usually have high environmen-



tal impacts.





     The overall efficiency of world energy use is between 6 and 8 per-




cent.  With due assessment to improvement of efficiency at every level



of conversion, storage, distribution and end use we could probably double




such a figure to between 10 and 15 percent overall.   That is we could




have twice as much power from conventional sources at the same energy



cost--with lower environmental cost.





     The variability of efficiency among the industrialized countries



illustrates this.  For example,  the energy required to produce an




                                   40

-------
arbitrary unit of Gross Domestic Product varies from 1.0 in Sweden to




1.3 in Japan and 1.9 in the United States.  That is, the United States




uses almost twice as much energy to produce the same unit of wealth as




Sweden.





     What is the feasibility of increasing efficiency?  Even with little




explicit attention to this, in the United States over the past 50 years




the amount of energy input per capita unit of GNP in the manufacturing




sector has declined steadily with a corresponding increase in overall




GNP.  The great increase in per capita energy use has been in transpor-




tation, service and domestic sectors particularly marked by low effici-




encies in conversion and end use.





     Increase in efficiency of energy use is, therefore, an obvious tar-




get for EPA research priorities—requiring attention to alternative energy




sources.  Many of the latter are less environmentally impacting,  and by




utilizing agricultural, industrial, and urban wastes may decrease envi-




ronmental problems in other areas.  They are, of course, poorly funded




in research and development due to institutional inertia and vested




interests in more conventional sources.





     When we turn to material resources the picture is obscured in much




the same fashion as energy.  There is all sorts of loose talk about re-




source shortages, needs to restrain production and restrain technologi-




cal development.





     By traditional practice, most of our data on metals and minerals




use are biased toward primary extraction and processing.  Beyond primary




production, it is progressively difficult to assess materials in use per




sector or product performance.  Rates of use and consumption figures




usually do not take into account the fact that we do not consume mate-




rials in use.   We use them in various combinations over time for differ-




ent purposes.
                                   41

-------
     Most of our metals are re-available after "use-lifetime" cycles in

products of from 3 to 25 years.   In many cases,  the recycling process

gains in efficiency of performance over the primary extraction cost of

the material—plus the fact of avoiding the large amounts of waste over-

burden in primary extraction.   We have,  however,  very few models of the

use, recycle process which have been developed specifically for the re-

duction of both performance and environmental costs.   Adequate large-

scale modeling of this type is an obvious EPA priority.

     This speaks not only to environmental and resource  conservation but

also to the reserves question in materials.   Conventional reserve esti-
mates are considered only in terms of unmined resources.   In effect,  how-
ever, our gross reserve includes all materials in use,  in "junk" stock-
pile form as well as in existing structures and  products.  Cumulative

production over time is, therefore, an index of  reserve  and in some cases

is from one-third to almost three times our estimated recoverable reserve

for many major metals.

     The question of materials (like the energy  question) is not one of

materials scarcity but of the sets of conventionally  preferred use ar-

rangements.  In economic as well as environmental terms,  it speaks to

the need for more comprehensive long-range research into  the following
two primary areas:

     (1)  How We May Use Our Materials More Efficiently  in Terms of
          Performance per Resource Unit Used.

          •  More systematic reuse and recycling practices.  It is
             estimated that approximately 55 percent  of  all copper
             put into use can eventually be recovered.   As against
             new copper mined with increased volumes  of  waste rock
             (at approximately 400 tons per ton  of usable copper),
             efficient reuse would double both conservation and
             economy if organized on a larger scale.
             In effect we need to reorganize our materials extraction
             and use system in more rational terms to close the waste,
                                   42

-------
              residuals  and  by-product  loops  in more efficient fashion.
              At  present each  section of the  industry operates in rel-
              ative  autonomy—extractive, primary processes, secondary
              manufacturers, marketing, and end-use.  Then there is a
              longer gap to  the  scrap industries.  The more rational
              mode would be  a  more  continuous systemic process with
              ongoing environmental assessments at each stage in the
              process.

           •  At  the production  and use end of the materials cycle,
              the obvious direction is build  the scrapping and re-use
              function in at the beginning.  That is to design prod-
              ucts for longer  life  cycles wherever appropriate, to
              design in  their  disassembly and recycling procedures,
              and to prepare anticipatory schedules for the recovery
              stages of  their  various materials.  This system has
              been partially introduced in the manufacture of mili-
              tary aircraft where costly alloys have their constitu-
              ent composition  stamped on the component to aid recovery
              on  scrapping.

     As we  began our discussion with the need for reconceptualization of

the overall  resource position,  so we now need to reconceptualize and re-
design our  industrial system  as a potentially regenerative one.

     (2)  Ranges of New Materials Coming into Use Require More Compre-
          hensive Environmental Attention.  This need not always be
          negative,  in  terms  of their projected impacts but may also
          be  turned toward their potential for replacement and sub-
          stitution for more  environmentally impacting uses.   For
          example,  as older materials such as steel give way to
          lighter metals, to  plastics and composites,  this may also
          afford gains  in economy and performance with equivalent
          reductions  in environmental costs.   Man-made fibers already
          off-loaded agricultural land from vegetable fibers,  increased
          food acreage  and potentially reduced environmental pressure
          for more  diverse land use.

     Again this  is  an area of environmental research which is presently

accorded only piecemeal  and relatively negative attention.  More compre-

hensive long-range  assessment policies are patently required.   The range

of developed and potential material substitutions may not only enhance

required supply  levels  but also have less impact on the environment.

                                   43

-------
     Technological development is obviously a crucial factor in the en-



vironmental aspects of energy and material resource uses.  The problem




here is that we tend to lump together all the different phases of



"industrial" technology.  We may distinguish at least three major phases




of industrial development with different sets of typical resource uses,




environmental impacts, and related socioeconomic changes.





     The first phase encompasses the heavy industry developments incident




upon the later stages of the Industrial Revolution--typically steelmaking,




railroads, automobiles, electrical generation,  and so forth,  based on the




fossil fuels.  This type of industrial practice is highly resource deple-




tive, with low performance per input of energy  and materials, and has




gross environmental impacts through its effluents and other by-products.




Although it still constitutes the industrial base of many societies,  it




is partially obsolete in its plant, production/consumption practices,  and



supporting materials policies.





     The second phase of industrial development trends toward the light



metals and plastics associated with the development of air transport,




aerospace, and computers—and the emerging set  of new electromagnetic




spectrum industries, i.e.  electronics, telecommunications,  and nuclear



energy which developed after World War II.   This phase,  is by comparison,



non-resource depletive, extremely economical in energy use and has a  much




lower impact on the environment.   Its advanced  technological  forms trend



toward ephemeralization through their decreasing use of  materials and




energy per function, and their successive microminiaturization of com-



ponents .





     The third phase might be characterized by  the development of new




ranges of metallic and nonmetallic composites and reinforced  materials




for structural purposes coupled with more sophisticated  electronic and



electrochemical processing and  the emergence of biotechnical  develop-




ments,  e.g.,  the resurgence of  industrial microbiology and bionic




                                   44

-------
engineering, the more efficient use of microbial populations to produce
energy, food and process materials, and the development of new ranges of

alternative energy sources.

     In practice of course, these phases overlap and have different rates

of growth and development.  In the advanced societies they are also paced

by changes in social and economic organization, in the balance of produc-

tion and services, and by internal shifts in manpower and resource re-

quirements.  Hence the shift from the first to the second and third

phases of such development is often phrased as from industrial to post-

industrial society—meaning really a shift to a different kind of indus-
trialization.

     One key factor in this shift, of relevance to our theme is that,

with the fusion of information and communications technology, information

(or organized knowledge) begins to emerge as the unique resource capabil-

ity.  Information as basic resource has certain unusual properties:

     •  All other resources and technics are ultimately dependent upon
        information and knowledge for their recognition,  evaluation,
        and development.

     •  Information as a social resource is not reduced or lessened
        by wider use or sharing like material resources—rather it
        gains in the process of distribution and exchange.

     Where previous resource bases such as raw materials and energy were,

by comparison,  scarce and depletive, information and knowledge are in-

exhaustible .  The enlarged environmental awareness in itself may be

largely due to increased capacities to perceive, monitor, and evaluate

environmental changes incident upon these new information and communi-

cations capabilities.   Certainly the attitudinal changes towards the

environment were greatly aided by the electronic media.

     The above review does not absolve uncontrolled technological growth

as a major factor in environmental deterioration nor does it advocate
                                   45

-------
technological deterioration.   It merely stresses the need  for more

adequate conceptual and policy frameworks for differentiating and eval-
uating the impacts of technology.   More immediate measures lie with ap-

propriate institutional change,  with  more stringent economic dis-

incentives to waste and pollute,  and  with more rigorous socioeconomic

and technological assessment.

     Our current assessment procedures  need  to be expanded in several

ways and are thus candidates for the  longer  range research needs  of the

EPA.

     (1)  The need to include institutional  and policy  assessment.
          That is, to recognize  that  the environment is not only
          modified by physical actions  but by our ideas, beliefs,
          and value systems—social,  economic,  cultural—and the
          ways in which they operate  to influence policies and
          environmental decisions  even  more  than material  tech-
          niques .
     (2)  That the industrial assessment process should be con-
          ceptually reorganized  to consider  both agriculture and
          industry together with their  product and service com-
          ponents as a whole system.   It should encompass  not
          only industrial  uses,  residuals, and pollutants  but
          also agri-industry equivalents and how these  are re-
          lated to domestic materials,  garbage,  and effluents.
          This would furnish a beginning description of our over-
          all environmental transactions as  the external metabolic
          system of society.   We have accumulated considerable sys-
          tematic knowledge about  the flows  of energy and  materials
          in our internal  metabolism, but our conceptual framework
          of our external  metabolic flows is singularly inadequate.

     (3)  All such assessments should be oriented towards  the longer
          range of the next 30 to  50  years (some perhaps beyond)  and
          should be prospective  by nature.   Our tendency thus far
          has been to restrict attention to  those impacts  that have
          already occurred rather  than  anticipating the possible
          impacts and cross-impacts of  processes before they are
          introduced.
                                  46

-------
     Moving to the life style changes which may be underway and which




might influence environmental policy, one can return provisionally to



the post-industrial shift hypothesis.





     This carries with it certain suggestions about growth, consumption,



and quality of life which may be important.  It is generally assumed



that, in the more advanced societies, material expectations and demands



for personal consumption will continue on an exponential curve—thereby



sustaining gross resource depletion and environmental deterioration.



The evidence seems otherwise.  It may be suggested that as standards of



living rise beyond sufficiency, we get satiation levels of demand.  Wants



may be artificially stimulated beyond this point but, as advertising



revenues show, this is a costly process.  The tendency is not toward just



more products and more things but toward wider ranges of alternative



choices of products and toward greater access to shared services.





     Material satisfaction in terms of individual consumption peaks out



below maximal satiation and then finds expression through progressively



dematerialized and, eventually symbolic means of satisfaction.





     At a low income level, the material and symbolic goal may be  a



large resource-hungry automobile.  As such goals become more easily



reachable, they tend to transform into an interest in smaller high-



performance cars thence to a recreative and "aesthetic" interest in



speed or driving generally.  Where food is scarce, being fat has high



social status.  In rich societies today it is the reverse—foods are



consumed for their low caloric value and some become merely symbols of



consumption rather than material actuality.





     There is an accompanying value shift observable where people  begin



to pursue styles of life and goals for personal growth which move  away



from the energy-intensive, materially costly and conspicuous consumption



of the earlier industrial society toward concerns with the meaning and
                                   47

-------
quality of life experience.   The expansion of shared  amenities such as




national parks, clean waters and beaches,  becomes important—even where




the individual may not use them,  he or she will  subscribe to their col-




lective availability as a drawdown on the  public purse.





     Overall this kind of social shift,  accompanied by  the technological




changes already described,  suggests that even the "growth" requirements




of more people can be satisfied with less  per capita  resources and less



environmental impact.  We should not,  however, assume some invisible




hand at work guiding these trends so that  it  all comes  out for the




better!  Many of the positive aspects of these changes  have to be an-




ticipated and aided rather than merely observed.





     Neither may we assume that most current  policy directions and leader-



ship will bring them about.   Indeed many of the  key change issues have




emerged not from leaders and policies but  from issue-oriented citizen



groups in the society--for example,  environmental conservation,  consum-



erism, and quality of life issues surfaced in this way  before they were



sanctified by policy attention.   This suggests that a key function for



EPA may also be the closer analysis and oversight of  social trends,  at-




titudinal changes, and value orientations  with their  appropriate long-




range projection in terms of environmental policies.





     In the larger sense,  we refer here to the longer range social and




political constraints that  may affect EPA  decisions.  Very often such




constraints on the wider demands for a better environment emerge not




from any broad consensus of the society but from the  specific interest




groups who have the power and lobbying pressure  to influence and con-




strain decisions far in excess of their representative  numbers.





     There is no fast answer to how a better  balance  of interests might



obtain.  The paradox often exists that those  who have such power to in-



fluence policies derive that power from public resources such as
                                   48

-------
federally leased lands, direct and indirect public subsidies,  and various

other means which flow ultimately from the citizen's purse.   Many of our

best environmental policies have been pursued in the face of opposition

from those with short-term political mandates or concerned with the most

economically expedient exploitation of environmental resources.  In gen-
eral, the emerging debate in this area may be characterized  as a conflict

between the politics of longer range social requirements and the shorter

range expediencies of "business as usual."

     Again, the balancing of these competing interests,  which  may aid or

constrain appropriate long-range policies, may well be a focus for EPA
research.  Certainly one component may be vital here—communication and

contact with the larger publics.  Information on both the key  issues and

on the intricacies of specific policies is often restricted  to those
special interest groups who may be opposed to their consequences.   The

EPA should forward more continuous appraisal and communications functions

both with expert groups acting in the public policy interest and with the
wider citizenry directly and through its various associational groupings.

     In concluding,  I have been asked to identify some priority research
topics which the EPA should undertake now.  I have mentioned a number of

these in dealing with various topic areas of my brief.   In order of pri-

ority they may be summarized as follows:


Generalized Program Priorities

     (1)   The development of a more comprehensive conceptual framework
          for environmental concern.   This would include the systemic
          interrelationship of resource usage patterns,  technological
          development,  and socioeconomic change.

     (2)   Larger scale  modeling of the industrial,  agricultural,  and
          urban systems.   These need  not,  and perhaps should not,  be
          initially  quantitative in cast.   It probably calls more
          directly for  a  broad "taxonomic" synthesis and mapping of
                                  49

-------
          the interactive  components  in  the overall  system  and  pro-
          jections  of  alternative  relationships and  tradeoffs.

     (3)   Expansion of the assessment process  to  include both tech-
          nological and institutional assessments oriented  specifi-
          cally towards prospective appraisal  of  their  longer range
          consequences and cross-impacts.

     (4)   Need for  a balance  of  more  integrative work with  reduct-
          ionist directions,  i.e., more  synthesis to pace analysis,
          or to combine analytical results into larger  policy
          oriented,  long-range,  frames of reference.
Specific Research  Priorities

     (1)   More efficient  and  less  environmental  impacting  resource
          usage.   This  would  involve detailed  energy and materials
          budgets  for specific product and service  flows,  oriented
          towards  increasing  performance per unit of invested re-
          sources  and the reduction of wastes  and residuals.

     (2)   An investigation of the  redesign of  major product and
          appliance  groups towards possibilities of longer life,
          built-in procedures for  scrapping and  reuse and  higher
          efficiency of operation  and maintenance.

     (3)   A  new materials assessment program in  terms of feasible
          substitutions both  for improved resource  performance and
          environmental impact.  This would obviously include the
          screening  of  new materials and products for their nega-
          tive effects  on the environment.

     (4)   The analysis  and projection of longer  range social needs
          and trends.   This would  encompass the  emergence  and
          identification  of changes in attitudes values and life
          styles in  the society and their projected consequences
          for changes in  environmental policy.

     (5)   Public communication and consultation.  The design of
          better procedures for public policy  appraisal by expert
          and public groups:  increased information dissemination
          on critical issues  and policies with wider exposure to
          public debate via the media.
                                  50

-------
     We may note that these summarized priorities are obviously inter-



linked.  The specific recommendations fold in as components of the gen-



eralized program priorities.   It should also be assumed that many of



these topic areas will require a global context for their more realistic



assessment rather than being confined only to the U.S.  national society



postures.
                                  51

-------
THE EMERGING SITUATION FOR RESOURCES—AN EXTRAPOLATIVE VIEW

                    Theodore J.  Gordon
                     The Futures Group
                 Glastonbury, Connecticut

-------
       THE  EMERGING  SITUATION FOR RESOURCES—AN EXTRAPOLATIVE VIEW

                           Theodore J. Gordon


 Introduction

      Both  the drives  for  increasing economic output and for increasing

 world population  require  continually increasing raw material use.  The

 world per  capita  mineral  consumption rate quadrupled over the past 25
       *
 years.   Assume for a moment that a similar rate increase will hold over

 the next 25 years.  In that same interval, world population will about

 double,  Therefore, by combining these two forces, by the year 2000, the

 world as a whole  may  increase its present mineral consumption by a factor

 of eight or so.   Failure  to achieve this growth will mean that developing

 countries will not  be able to achieve their current economic goals.

      The dilemma  implied  by this tremendous growth rate is illustrated in

 Figure 1.  Since  1945 annual world production of the indicated mineral

 has doubled every seven or eight years, while in the United States the

 production doubling rate  was approximately 25 years.  In 1945 the United

 States consumed about 60  percent of the world total for the minerals

 shown; by 1971, primarily because of the growth of consumption of other

 nations in the world,  this figure had fallen to 16 percent.

     This huge increasing demand for raw materials has enormously impor-

 tant  consequences.  The economic condition of the United States depends,
*Eugene N.  Cameron, "U.S.  Contribution to Mineral Supplies," Mineral
 Position of the United States,  1975-2000,  p.  21 (Madison,  Wise.,  Uni-
 versity of Wisconsin Press,  1973).

                                    55

-------
       o
       or
       LU
       5
0
in
O
          1.6
           1.4
           1.2
   1.0
           .8
                                    World production
                                         U.S. consumption
                                    ,-„••- U.S. production
            0
     1930   1940
                         1950   I960
                           YEAR
1970
1980
Data compiled at the University of Wisconsin by Kenneth D. Markart
and E. N. Cameron, from U. S. Bureau of Mines,  MINERALS YEARBOOK
AND COMMODITY DATA SUMMARIES.   From MINERAL POSITION OF THE UNITED
STATES, 1975-2000, p.  19  (Madison, Wise.,  University of Wisconsin
Press, 1973.)
FIGURE I.  1930-1971 WORLD PRODUCTION AND UNITED STATES
          PRODUCTION AND CONSUMPTION OF EIGHTEEN MINERALS
          (Iron Ore, Bauxite, Copper, Lead, Zinc, Tungsten, Chromium,
          Nickel, Molybdenum, Manganese, Tin, Vanadium, Fluorspar,
          Phosphate, Cement, Gypsum, Potash, and Sulfur)
                                56

-------
in large measure, on the continued availability of reasonably priced,



economically  important materials.  With growing competition for these



resources on  a world market, our economy becomes more dependent on world



economic and  political conditions.  To the degree that countries depend



on imports, opportunities abound for OPEC-like cartels.  The environment



is likely to  be  severely stressed in an effort to produce and dispose of



the demanded  materials.  And, perhaps most disturbing of all, the de-



pletion of some  economically viable resources is possible in our life-



time.





     These factors have led to the argument that consumption must be cur-



tailed, that  society must somehow be reoriented toward other measures of



achievement,  that nonindustrial models and goals must be found—not only



for the United States, but for all nations—and that, in fact, many na-



tions of the  world are in the midst of such a transition currently.  This



is one plank  in  the "limits to growth" platform.





     The central point of the "limits to growth" argument is irrefutable;



exponential growth of world population and resource-depleting production



must ultimately  end--the issues are when and how.





     In this  paper I answer "neither the growth of population or resource



depleting production is likely to end very soon."   The difficulty of in-



fluencing population growth rate is well known.  Even if the world birth-



rate dropped  markedly and quickly, the world population would almost cer-



tainly reach  six billion by 2000 (versus four billion currently).   To



imagine a very rapid transition from the current consumption and economic



growth orientation to society based on new cultural values (or if not new



values than at least a value structure based on vastly different priori-



ties)  is difficult indeed.   The system inertia is  too high;  the lessons



of the culture too strong;  the levels of expectations too high in the



United States and elsewhere.   The reward structure of corporations, the



expectations of people about what constitutes a "good life," the popular




                                   57

-------
images of "progress" and "status," the whole notion of Gross National

Product (GNP~)  and GNP growth as a measure of achievement all suggest that

our present culture, and indeed the culture of all developed nations,

requires not only consumption but increasing consumption.

     This consumption-oriented growth-oriented culture is  not unique to

the United States; it is the culture of industrialized nations.   Further-

more, many developing countries form their economic goals  on the model of

the developed  countries.  In developed countries economic  growth is ap-

parently a necessity, at least for the short term,  to keep unemployment

low, to remain competitive internationally,  to satisfy system imperatives

of their complex economic structure and,  some economists argue,  to per-

mit less affluent individuals to achieve  higher living standards either

through transfer payments or through other redistribution  mechanisms.

In developing  countries growth in output  is  seen as a birthright,  a path

to affluence,  well chartered by the United States and other nations.

     So we are on a collision path.   Reserves are needed in increasing

amounts as a result of growing economies  and populations;  yet providing

them will be chaotic, perhaps disastrous.

     Perhaps expectations and values and  economic structures can change

fast enough, but I doubt it.   Where then  does that leave us?  Sorely in

need of more time.  Technology,  informed  and sensitive technology,  mech-

anical as well as social technology,  can  help buy time and mitigate the

impacts of growing mineral use.   We have  little choice but to define

what would be  helpful and to pursue it.

     In this paper I plan to:

     •  Review some of the reasons for the chaos.

     •  Describe the slow transitions which  are apparently already
        underway.

     •  Propose some technological and policy alternatives that  might
        improve the situation.

                                   58

-------
Some Reasons for Chaos

     The rising world demand for raw materials suggests that the United

States, for the first time, is likely to face a situation of continually

rising, unpredictable prices and uncertainty of supply of many  materials.

To meet its needs, the United States has to depend increasingly upon  im-

ports of certain materials—domestic production has lagged behind demand
(see Table 1) . "I"

     Dependence on imports seems almost certain to grow.   As shown in
Figure 2, under the assuumption of continued economic growth in the United

States, reasonable projections indicate that by 2000,  imports will account

for more than 90 percent or more of all the chromium,  tin,  titanium,  plat-
inum, beryllium, aluminum, and fluorine the country consumes.

     A paradigm for forecasting future OPEC-like situations might be  to

identify key materials used by industrial nations which are concentrated

in a few other nations that could be linked politically.   The paradigm

becomes particularly strong if the recipient countries do not have access
*Some of the material in this section is drawn from:  L.  Heston  and H.  S.
 Becker, Focal Points in the Future of Food and Mineral  Resources, Report
 151-46-10 (Glastonbury,  Conn.,  The Futures Group,  July  1974),  and T.  J.
 Gordon, Shortages and Their Implications for American Business, Report
 132-59-01 (Glastonbury,  Conn.,  The Futures Group,  March 1974).
tMaterial Needs and Environment  Today and Tomorrow, Final  Report of  the
 National Commission on Materials Policy, pp.  9-8 (Washington,  D.C.,
 June 1973).
*U.S. Department of the Interior, First Annual Report of the  Secretary
 of the Interior;  under the Mining and Minerals Policy Act of 1970  (P.L.
 91-631), p.  63 (Washington,  D.C.,  1972)  and Material Needs and the  En-
 vironment Today and Tomorrow, Final Report of the  National Commission on
 Materials Policy,  pp.  2-25 (Washington,  D.C., June 1073).   (Hereafter
 called U.S.  Department of the Interior,  First Annual Report  and Material
 Needs.)
                                   59

-------
                 Table  I

  CHANGING UNITED STATES  RELIANCE UPON
     SELECTED MATERIALS FROM ABROAD
                 Imports  as  a  Percent  of
                 Total  U.S.  Consumption
Material
Aluminum
Copper
Lead
Mercury
Platinum
Tin
Titanium
Zinc
Iron ore
Chromium
Cobalt
Columbium
Manganese
Nickel
Tungsten
Petroleum
Natural gas
Timber
1950
71
35
59
92
91
100
32
37
6
100
92
100
77
99
80
8
0
11
1970
86
8
40
38
98
100
47
60
14
100
96
100
94
91
40
22
3
8
Change
+ 15
-27
-19
-54
+ 7
--
+15
+23
+ 8
—
+ 4
—
+17
- 8
-40
+ 14
+ 3
- 3
Source:   Material  Needs  and  Environment
         Today and Tomorrow,  Final  Report
         of the National Commission on
         Materials Policy, pp.  8-9
         (Washington,  D.C.,  June 1973).
                    60

-------
                            1970
                                                     1985
2000
                         PERCENTAGE "              PERCENTAGE "             PERCENTAGE "
                  0   20   40   60   80  100 0   20   40   60   80  100 0   20  40   60   80   100
CHROMIUM
TIN
TITANIUM, METAL
PLATINUM
BERYLLIUM
NICKEL
ALUMINUM
ASBESTOS
FLOURINE
POTASSIUM
TITANIUM, NONMET.
SILVER
LEAD
IRON
MAGNESIUM, NONMET.
SODIUM
CALCIUM
MAGNESIUM, METAL
NITROGEN, COMP.
SILICON
SULFUR

NO OAT A AVAILABLE

' '• '• •••••::.\
!'."> ;;AIA AVAILABLE
•' .': . •'" ::'': )
. . ',' :' \
	 : • ••••; : .1
• .. •• '.' • :•''•• ,vj
j
J
;_."_JTL_ : _ ~
! •••••]
\ ..•:• i 	 • ~
i
p" "" 	 "


• -

i
i 	 	 „ . .... -

























	 	 i
i
	 j
i
	 i
	 i
,1
	 1
I

\
•j-__— - _

i
I
, I
.;..!


























	 I
I

	 I

f
I
...J


|
j
I
	 \
I
*f\
m^mv-ymi
                   MAJOR FOREIGN  SOURCES

              USSR, SOUTH AFRICA, TURKEY
              MALAYSIA, THAILAND, BOLIVIA
              AUSTRALIA
              UK, USSR, S.AFRICA,CAN.,NOR.,JAP.

              CANADA, NORWAY
              JAMAICA, SURINAM, CANADA,AUSTRALIA
              CANADA, SOUTH AFRICA
              MEXICO, SPAIN, ITALY, S.  AFRICA
              CANADA
              CANADA, AUSTRALIA
              CAN. , PERU, MEX. , HON., AUSTRALIA
              CAN., PERU, MEXICO, AUSTRALIA
              CAN., JAPAN, VENEZUELA, EEC
              GREECE, IRELAND
                      2C   43  60   80  100 0   20   40   60   80  100 0   20   40   60   80  100
                         SHORTFALL
                         DOMESTIC PRIMARY PRODUCTION
"BASED ON UtlGHT
  SOURCE:   U.S.  Department of  the  Interior, FIRST ANNUAL REPORT OF THE SECRETARY  OF THE  INTERIOR,
           under the Mining and Minerals Policy Act of 1970 (P.L. 91-631) (Washington,  D.C.,  1972),
           p.  63; and MATERIAL NEEDS AND THE ENVIRONMENT TODAY AND TOMORROW,  Final Report  of  the
           National Commission on  Material Policy, pp. 2-25 (Washington, B.C.,  June 1973).
                               FIGURE  2.  DIFFERENCE BETWEEN U.S. MATERIAL SUPPLY AND DEMAND

-------
to economically viable substitutes.   Figure  2  presents  some possible

groupings.*

     It does not appear that the world  will  be depleted of any major

mineral resource in this century.   This statement is  based on the fol-

lowing assumptions:

     (1)  World rate of consumption of  raw materials  will  continue
          to increase exponentially.  Projected growth  rates run
          from 1.1 percent per year for tin  to 6.4 percent per
          year for aluminum.

     (2)  Known reserves will increase  by a  factor of five before
          the turn of the century.   This assumption is  intended
          to capture the effect of  price elasticity:   as the
          resource nears depletion,  its price  will rise; as
          prices rise, there is additional incentive  for explo-
          ration and recovery of previously  marketable  resources.
          This "factor of five" assumption could, of  course, be
          wrong.'

     Using these preconditions, the length of  time remaining before

depletion of important nonrenewable natural  resources in the world can

be computed.  While it is true that these figures indicate depletion of

important materials will not occur in this century, they demonstrate,

nevertheless, that depletion is near.  As depletion nears, we can ex-

pect increasing prices, intensified arguments  for resource conservation,

hasty  searches for substitute materials, and increased government regu-

lation of the use of material.  All of these forces are inflationary
 *U. S. Department of the Interior, First Annual Report and Material Needs
 tThese  assumptions and the figures shown in the text are from Donella
  H. Meadows,  et al., The Limits to Growth  (New York, Universe Books,
  1972).   In  their computations, the known  global reserves were derived
  from U.S. Bureau of Mine estimates.
                                   62

-------
and will cause balance of payment difficulties as well as fluctuations

in the value of currency.
                      Resource
                   Aluminum
                   Chromium
                   Coal
                   Cobalt
                   Copper
                   Gold
                   Iron
                   Lead
                   Manganese
                   Mercury
                   Molybedenum
                   Natural gas
                   Nickel
                   Petroleum
                   Platinum group
                   Silver
                   Tin
                   Tungsten
                   Zinc
Remaining Years
 to Depletion
       55
      154
      150
      148
       48
       29
      173
       64
       94
       41
       65
       49
       96
       50
       85
       42
       61
       72
       50
     Estimates of mineral resources change over time.   The reserves  are

reduced by production, as well as by decreases in prices,  increases  in

costs, increased availability of substitute sources,  or government reg-

ulations that restrict the production and/or use of different  materials.

On the other hand, reserves may be enlarged by new discoveries and by

new technological or economic developments making it  feasible  to  produce

from deposits that previously had proved uneconomical  to mine.  There-

fore,  the future of mineral resources supply in the United States de-

pends not only on presently minable deposits already  identified,  but on
*U.S.  Department of the Interior,  First Annual Report and Material  Needs.
                                  63

-------
potential resources as well;  these resources include similar quality

deposits as yet undiscovered  and lower quality deposits which may prove


worthwhile at some point in the future.


     If shortages developed in materials for which indigenous but un-

tapped reserves exist, they would undoubtedly be developed.   Vincent E.

McKelvey, Chief of the United States Geological Survey, believes that at

higher prices, most of our mineral needs could be met through the turn
                                                                         jj;
of the century at Least, by using materials which lie within our borders.

However, among materials not  to be found in quantity in the United States

are tin, manganese, and chromite.  Furthermore, developing these resources

would undoubtedly have significant environmental and political ramifica-

tions.  The environmental implications are obvious;  as for the political,

we already hear dissatisfaction expressed by a state rich in one or

another mineral, which feels  exploited when it must  "export" the mineral

at the expense of its environment to satisfy the need of another state.

To put it more precisely:  why must Louisiana export its natural gas

when the state itself is in short supply?  Why should Montana suffer

strip mining when the coal finds its use out of the  state?  The argu-

ments are reminiscent of those used by developing countries.




The Transition in Progress


     There is an inexorable relationship between the size of an economy

and its consumption of materials and energy.  Certainly there is some

"scatter" which represents more or less efficiency or special condition,

but by and large, the correlation between consumption and output is

strong.  This is illustrated for energy consumption in Figure 3.  Some
*"Raw Material:  U.S. Grows More Vulnerable to Third World Cartels,"
  Science  (January 18, 1974).
                                   64

-------
200
                                                                 15%

                                                              REDUCTION

                                                              OF ENERGY
            V
     ARGENTINA^ ^ . |TALY
50O
                         1000        I50O        2000


                       GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT- $ /capita
                                                            2500
                                                          3000
   Source: E. Cook, "The Flow of Energy in an Industrial Society,

          SCIENTIFIC AMERICAN (September 1971), p. 142.
      FIGURE 3. RELATIONSHIPS BETWEEN ENERGY AND GNP (1968)
                                  65

-------
of the variation around the trend line in this figure can be accounted

for by differences in weather and lifestyle preferences,  particularly

with respect to transportation.   Such relationships offer at least a clue

about how much might be saved through conservation without requiring mas-

sive economic changes in a country; targets of more than 15 percent would

probably be very difficult to achieve.

     Despite the strong correlation between input mineral requirements

and economic activity, there are some indications that things are chang-

ing.  First of all, we are indeed in the midst of a transition to a more

service-oriented economy.  A smaller percentage of the labor force is and

will be  engaged in agriculture and manufacturing; the service sector--

including government—is growing.  Within ten years or so, only one

worker  in four or five (versus one in three currently) will be in manu-

facturing;  fewer than one  in 20, in agriculture.  Such an economy will

be less  energy and material demanding.

     Secondly, for some materials at  least, long term efficiency-

improvement trends seem to be in progress.  Since the early 1920s the

U.S. energy/GNP ratio  has  been in a falling trend, as more intensive use

of energy was offset by increased technical efficiency.  From 1966

through  1970  the trend reversed  itself and the  ratio moved steadily up-

wards.   This  had alarming  implications for the  future, and there has been

much speculation that  if the rise continued it  would  lead to even more

drastic  energy shortages than had been predicted.  In 1971 and 1972, how-

ever,  the ratio resumed its downward  direction.  Both the National Pet-

roleum  Council and the Bureau of Mines of the U.S. Department of  the

 Interior* anticipate that  the ratio will continue  to  fall in the  future.
 *Dupree,  W.  and  R.  West,  U.S.  Energy Through Year  2000  (Washington,  D.C.,
  U.S.  Department of the  Interior, December  1973).

                                    66

-------
Figure 4 depicts this history and a forecast of the project development

of the ratio which was made recently in a study by The Futures  Group.*
1 1 U
100
0.
* 8°
cr
8 60
cr
DO 40
Q

-------
half of a representative sample of people in the United States, ques-



tioned about the number of children which,  in their view,  constituted



an ideal family, answered, "four or more."   Now the fraction of people



holding that view is considerably less than a quarter.   Polling services



that track values, such as Yankelovich's Monitor,  have identified "fore-



runner" values groups in society holding nontraditional values:  the



forerunners, the new comformists, and the autonomous sectors.   Among



these groups is found beliefs in new, less  materialistic ways  to measure



success, rejection of the orderly and rational in favor of the less



planning and more spontaneous life,  and  the notion that simpler and



small is beautiful.





     Yet, the changes that are underway  are small  indeed in view of the



magnitude of the problem.  And they are  not always what they seem to be.



A person advocating a simpler life and less materialism, might still



include his stereo and electric guitar in his lifestyle.
Some Technologies and Policies That Might Be Helpful





     Scientific and technical developments will  be urgently important in



solving material problems.  Technology could have an  important role to




play in providing substitutions,  improving processing efficiencies,




promoting recycling and reuse, developing economic processes for the use




of lower grade ores, and in improving techniques of exploration and



recovery.





     In the area of exploration,  clearly improved methods would be use-




ful in helping to identify the location of mineral deposits, both in the



United States and throughout the  world.  These techniques include, for



example:
                                  68

-------
     •  Geological techniques,  including field work,  aerial surveys,
        subsurface investigations,  mapping or rock types,  and petro-
        logical studies.

     •  Aerial or orbital surveys using visible light,  infrared,  and
        microwave photography,  as well as gravimetric and  magnetic
        sensing.

     •  Geochemical exploration involving analyses performed on solid,
        liquid, and gaseous samples derived from surface manifestations
        and drilling cores.

     •  Geophysical techniques  including measurements of temperatures,
        electrical conductivity,  propagation velocity of elastic  waves,
        and density and magnetic  susceptibility of various strata.

     •  Seismographic techniques  including active or  passive seismic
        methods (active methods include reflective and refractive;
        passive techniques involve recording naturally generated
        microearthquakes or acoustic noise patterns within prescribed
        frequency ranges).

     •  Electrical methods including self-polarization,  induced
        polarization, and telluric approaches.

     In addition to simply developing improved methods for identifying

the location of resource deposits,  general improvements in the field of

geology would probably be very  helpful.  These improvements could lead

to the development of statistical and mathematical methods for projecting
the extent of the deposits, given certain surface and subsurface  geologic
            f
information.
*T.  J.  Gordon,  et al.,  A Technology Assessment of Geothermal Energy,  Re-
 port 164-46-11 (Glastonbury,  Conn., The Futures Group,  September 1974).
tL.  Heston and  H. S. Becker, Focal Points in the Future  of Food and
 Mineral Resources,  Report 151-46-10 (Glastonbury, Conn.,  The Futures
 Group, July 1974).   (Hereafter called Mineral Resources.)
                                   69

-------
     The mineral  position  of  the  United  States  might  also be improved

through the development  of new mining technologies.   The industry in

general is in a depressed  state,  as  evidenced by  the  relatively slow

advance of mining technology  and  the large  number of  imported technolo-
gies.  The National Academy of Sciences  recently  recommended several

potential research programs associated with improved  mining technology.

For example:

    "in conventional approaches there is a  need to determine whether
     harder cutting materials can be synthesized  in suitable sizes
     and shapes (tungsten  carbide and synthetic diamond have led to
     considerable progress in this respect), and  to explore their
     capabilities in factors  affecting bit  performance in various
     types of rock.  Novel approaches for both  soft and hard rock
     should be fully explored and evaluated for various mining con-
     ditions.  These include  the  use of  high powered  lasers, elec-
     tron beam, plasma torches, thermal  fragmentation, ultrasonics
     and shock waves, percussion  and hydraulic  jet techniques, and
     automated continuous  explosive systems.

     "it is recommended that  research be accelerated  on ways to
     automate mining operations.   Such automation requires the
     development of suitable  sensing devices (to  monitor rock
     composition, for example), information processing equipment
     (minicomputers), and  servo-mechanisms  (robots),  all of which
                                     t r -k
     have to be exceptionally rugged.

     Scientific and technological developments  will also be important

in the economic utilization of lower grade  ores.   The country will move
from the use of its richest ores to those that  are currently marginal.

Therefore, a series of developments that improve the  economics of the
use of low grade ore will  be necessary;  these  may involve for example,
in situ  leaching of ore deposits, improving methods of beneficiation

(e.g., beneficiation of magnetic taconite in coarse crushing plants in
*Mineral Resources.

                                  70

-------
the process of producing iron),  lower cost transportation,  new grinding

and separation techniques, diminished energy requirements,  etc.

     Ocean mining is a particularly promising era.   Here the processes

involve both the removal of minerals from sea water through distillation

or osmotic processes and the direct recovery of minerals from the ocean

floor.  Sea water contains almost all of the chemical elements,  although

only four elements—sodium, chlorine, magnesium,  and bromine—are now

being recovered in relatively large quantities.  Landsberg,  Fishman,
and Fisher project that:

     It is not unreasonable to expect that within the next  twenty
     to forty years some byproduct recovery will  be carried out  in
     sea water conversion plants built for meeting fresh water
     needs.  But these plants will probably be of a limited number
     in the United States, at least in this century; barring the
     achievement of the extremely low-processing costs,  application'
     will probably not be of major significance except for  the sea
     water minerals already being recovered.'

     With respect to use of the ocean bottom, mineral resources  may be

"mined" from beneath the surface of the Continental Shelf,  recovered in

the form of deposits from silt,  slime, and solid debris covering the

ocean floor (these materials are believed to have collected from land

erosion and deterioration of submerged rock), and nodular material lying

on the ocean bottom, at considerable depth.  The recovery of nodules is

particularly interesting since they appear to be primarily  manganese and

also contain nickel, copper, and cobalt.  Nodules have been found at

depths of from 500 to 3000 feet off the United States southeast  coast,

and to a range of 5000 to 14,000 feet in the eastern Pacific Ocean.
^Mineral Facts and Problems, Bureau of Mines Bulletin 650,  United States
 Department of the Interior (1970).
tH.  H.  Landsberg, L.  L.  Fishman, and J. L.  Fisher,  Resources in America's
 Future, 1963, p. 495.   (Hereafter called Resources in America's Future.)
                                  71

-------
     ...one square  mile would  contain  70,000  tons of  nodules  or
     20,000 to  35,000  tons of  manganese...a breakthrough here
     would almost at once shake  free the United  States of  growing
     dependence upon overseas  sources.  Recovery of phosphates
     from the ocean bottom,  especially along  the west coast,  may
                              *
     exceed that of manganese.

     Recycling  technology is indeed promising.   Americans  discard ap-

proximately 250 million tons of  solid  wastes  per year.  Today nearly all
major materials are to some  extent  recycled.  The rate varies from nearly

100 percent for lead  to 50 percent  for copper,  31 percent  for iron and

steel, and 19 percent  for paper  and board,  to 4.2 percent  for glass.
Considering just iron  and steel,  nonferrous metals, glass,  textiles, and

rubber, about 25 percent of  the  materials  consumed  in the  country are
currently recycled.  Improved  processes of recovery for the huge  waste
stream will reduce  demand  for  virgin materials.  The  National Commission

on Materials Policy has recommended that  the  government accelerate re-
search and development and  technology  transfer  on resource recovery from

scrap, especially encouraging  the recovery of resources  in municipal

waste.*

     Finally, science and  technology  can  aid  in the development  of sub-
stitute materials for currently  imported  minerals or  minerals that are

likely to be in short supply in  the future.   Several  of  these substitu-

tions are already in progress; for example,  the use of  plastics  for

metals in automobiles began in 1960 and had reached a level of  about
 ^Resources in America's Future, p. 496.
 t"Report  to Congress on Resource Recovery," Environmental Protection
 Agency  (February 1973).
 $Needs in the Environment, Today and Tomorrow:  Final Report of the
 National Commission on Materials Policy, p. 4d-19  (June 1973).  Here-
 after called Needs in the Environment.
                                   72

-------
10 percent by 1970.*  The National Academy of Sciences recently urged

that the search for substitute materials begin immediately:

     We cannot emphasize too strongly that the discovery and de-
     velopment of new and improved materials as possible substi-
     tutes for existing ones takes time, and that the process is
     generally driven by clearly perceived functional objectives
     rather than by ill-placed optimism that "something will turn
     up when the crunch comes."T

     There are three major difficulties encountered in seeking to sub-

stitute one material for another:  complexity of design considering

specialized uses; accounting for the many uses of single materials of

different combinations; and accommodating the huge volume of use of many

commodities.  In technically complex applications, such as nuclear reac-

tors and jet engines, some substitute materials are nearly impossible to

find.  In other cases, the material is so crucial to adequate performance

(e.g., palladium in telephone systems) that a substitute would mean re-

design of the entire system if that were possible.

     There are many political actions possible in this domain that relate

to creating incentives or removing barriers to influence production or

consumption of minerals.  For example, taxes or subsidies could be
created to promote conservation of scarce resources, federal stockpiling

programs could be introduced, or materials rationed.  As a single example,

the Congressional Office of Technology Assessment recently pointed out

that more than a hundred million acres of federal lands including wild-

life refuges,  national parks, and land administered by the Department of

Defense are hardly used to produce materials, yet these lands are thought
*J.  C. Fisher and R.  H. Pry,  "A Simple Substitution Model of Technologi-
 cal Change," Technological Forecasting and Social Change, Vol.  Ill,
 No. 1, p.  75.
tMineral Resources.
                                   73

-------
to be quite rich in mineral  wealth.   The various institutional factors

that affect the use of such  land include:

     •  Environmental  policy,  laws,  and regulations.

     •  Mining and leasing laws and  regulations.

     •  Administrative processes for environmental and other
        certification  reviews.
     •  Economic policy (e.g.,  tax provisions such as depletion
        allowances and accelerated amortization of facilities or
        investment tax credit).
     •  Transportation policy (e.g., construction and operation
        of rail lines) .
     •  Government programs for geological and geophysical sur-
        veying, exploration and mapping.
     •  Conflicting or concurrent federal-state jurisdictions
        (e.g., sovereignty and unitization of oil fields involving
        federal lands).*

     The National Commission of Materials Policy recently recommended a

full legislative program in this area.  They urged that federal agencies

intensify  their efforts to encourage worldwide development of resources

by all means, diplomatic, financial, and educational; that the federal

government give users of materials  economic incentives in the form of

tax  credits for expanded use of recycling materials; and that Congress

modify the existing General Mining  law  to modify the procedure for re-

claiming abandoned mining claims.   They urged that prospectors should

be  granted sufficient rights to encourage their active exploration for
                      t
new mineral deposits.

     Corporations  that have the use of  materials  in  short supply will be,

 I think, seen by  the  government and society as  custodians entrusted with
 *Request  for  Proposal  from  the Office of Technology Assessment:   OTA/RP
  75-4 (February  1975).
 fNeeds in the Environment.

                                   74

-------
the job of changing those materials into products useful to the country.

There will be penalties for performing this job badly and rewards for
doing it well.  Within a corporation that has under its control the use
of materials in short supply, there will be new kinds of decisions about
what to manufacture and produce.  With input materials limited, it may
not be possible to serve all markets and produce all products;  what should
be given priority?  If business has no means for deciding,  government
will.


Summa ry

     In preparing the agenda for this symposium, EPA posed  several ques-
tions.  In this section, based on the foregoing discussion, summary
answers to these questions are presented.

     (1)  What future resource issues do you anticipate will have
          major implications for EPA policy?
          •  Determination of more precise relationships between
             consumption of minerals and GNP.
          •  Public attitudes and expectation about what constitutes
             a "good life."
          •  World competition for minerals, availability and price.
          •  Extent of domestic proven reserves, their locations,
             and the willingness of the owners (including the
             federal government) and local and state governments
             to permit their extraction.
          •  The availability and cost of substitutes.
     (2)  How will various changes in human carrying capacities affect
          these issues?
          •  GNP growth and the material things it brings will  con-
             tinue to be sought by individuals and the nation as a
             whole.
                                   75

-------
     •  Shortages and high prices of materials will bring pres-
        sure  to  develop  indigenous  resources and more advanced
        technologies of  waste processing, recycling, explora-
        tion,  substitutes, and  improved production and proc-
        essing efficiency.
(3)   What  emerging  environmental policy alternatives will need
     to  be examined in light of these issues?
     •  Current  policies should be  reviewed to determine that
        they  encourage the development of needed technology and
        are not  inconsistent with the effective and appropriate
        development and  use of  indigenous resources.

     •  Policies will be needed to  improve planning associated
        with  projecting  the future  demand for minerals.

(4)   What  political and  social  constraints may limit the effects
     of  EPA policy  decisions?

     •  Suppose  materials are short, prices high, supply uncer-
        tain,  and unemployment  pervasive.  EPA policy decisions
        which are seen (correctly or incorrectly) to inhibit
        the effective development of indigenous supplies will
        be strenuously questioned.  In other words, in this
        scenario, a backlash is indeed plausible.

(5)   In  view  of  future issues, what kinds of research related to
     resource use should EPA be undertaking now?

     •  Supporting  the development  of more effective exploration
        techniques, and  geology in  general.

     •  Participating in the evolution of new mining technologies.

     •  Pursuing the techniques for employing lower grade ores
        and beneficiation.

     •  Investigating the utility of ocean mining.

     •  Reaching an understanding and creating incentives for
        greatly  intensifying recycling and waste processing
        technologies.

     •  Understanding a  priori, the dynamics and potential for
        the use  of  substitutes  for  materials likely to be in
        short supply.

     •  Developing  more  effective economic and planning tools
        which help  project the  primary and secondary conse-
        quences  of  policy.
                             76

-------
RESOURCES, INDUSTRY,  AND THE ENVIRONMENT

           Maurice R. Eastin
 Special Assistant to the Administrator
  U.S. Environmental  Protection Agency

-------
                RESOURCES, INDUSTRY,  AND THE ENVIRONMENT



                           Maurice R. Eastin








     EPA's charter from Congress is to set health standards and  to  en-



force such standards.  If we in EPA were to look at this charter without



relation to the total environment, we could be accused properly  of  tunnel



vision.  If on the other hand we were completely broad in our interpre-



tation we would give into other forces and our charter would suffer.



Russell Train is consciously trying to operate reasonably within these



bounds with one eye on health and the other on our economy.   This is  the



decision of a reasonable and prudent man.





     Our government is a system as well.  What OSHA,  Agriculture, Energy,



Transportation, Interior, EPA do is all interdependent.   At times,  how-



ever, we give the impression that each segment of government is  afflicted



with tunnel vision or that government is a series of  tunnels with no  view



from the mountain top.





     If every agency takes its pound of flesh, the body politic  will  die.



Administrators must decide whether they will be technicians or statesmen,



picayune or wise,  capricious or profound.  Government also has an alarm-



ing proclivity for going from suspicion to conclusion with quite careless



attention to the burden of proof.   This is in many cases generated by



an overdeveloped sense of self-righteousness and turns into unresponsive




and arrogant government.





     The dictionary is one of our great educational tools.  It is also



good for the soul  now and then.  The other day I decided to refer to  it



for some basic guidance.  Health standards, as you know, are created  to



guide us all in environmental reconstruction.   We can argue about them
                                   79

-------
quantitatively,  but I believe we all  accept their objective.   By defini-




tion health is:   "The general condition of the body."  We assume,  of




course,  that this includes the brain  or mind and that the objective is




good health.  Thus, the definition helps to point out the obvious—that




health is dependent on the condition  of the total body, considered as a




system.





     Now what about the definition of environment.   Webster says it is




"the aggregate of the social  and cultural" conditions that influence the




life of an individual or community.   The word aggregate stood out  and I




looked that up:   aggregate is a mass  or body of units or parts somewhat




loosely assocated with one another.   The term associated led  me to the



definition of system:  "a regularly interacting or interdependent  group




of units or forces forming a  unified  whole and tending to be  in equi-




librium. "





     Combining these definitions,  we  come to the conclusion that the



environment is the aggregate  of the interdependent interacting physical,




cultural, economic, and social conditions,  generally in equilibrium and




that influence the life of the individual or community.





     That is quite an impressive mouthful indeed.





     The physical system within the total environmental system includes




the air, water and land.   It  therefore follows that in dealing with



water you are disturbing this interrelated air and land and you are at




the same time disturbing cultural,  economic,  social factors which  before



such action were loosely in equilibrium.





     Man however at the present time  does not completely understand the



total life or environmental system.   To solve or to make progress  to-




wards the understanding of such a complex subject,  our teachers have




always told us to seek out a  portion  of the system, work with it,  under-




stand it, and use it as a building block to progressively reach our goal





                                  80

-------
The Guiding Philosophy for the Future





     I am convinced that the building block that we should use as a key



to total understanding is the process—a subsystem of the total mystery —



but a building block we understand nevertheless.  If we look towards a



more efficient process from the viewpoint of resources, economics,  and



energy, the environment will gain.





     It is therefore a point of view we seek; a more technologically and



system-oriented posture than the narrow view of pollutants coming out



the end of a pipe.  These are only indicators of the performance of the



total system we seek to correct.  And we are seeking progress not per-



fection.  We cannot live with the economics of the end-of-the pipe point



of view.






Application of Philosophy to Program Administration





     But what can EPA do administratively to face up to the system con-



cept and lead Congress into eventually using the system concept in draft-



ing laws.  I reemphasize that we at EPA must interface administratively



water, air, and earth laws and second, effectively and efficiently ab-



sorb and understand industry technology and the processess—the building



of the organization to do the job.  The equally important manning of that



organization and the quality of management will be left to another time.





     At present, the whole energy is law oriented.  I hold that this is



the proper organization for the enforcement sections of EPA—and EPA is



an enforcement agency; but I believe most deeply that this law orienta-



tion is in error for the program areas of EPA.  We are now requiring



municipal officials, agriculture and industry—the people we all must



depend upon to get the job done—to mill about from pillar to post to



seek out the receiving areas for technology and to be whip-sawed from



water to air to earth to obtain incomplete nonsystem oriented decisions.
                                   81

-------
If we do not arrive at a system decision within our agency,  how can




industry plan and execute programs in the best interest of all our citi-



zens?  At the best, it is awkward and at the worst this loose adminis-




tration is irresponsible.





     But I do not believe this is happening because collectively EPA is




bad or stupid or does not mean well.   I  am convinced that this is hap-



pening because our program area is not system-oriented.   It  is oriented




and organized and fragmented—as is the  rest of the agency—by air,




water, and earth laws.





     I believe the day will come when the agency will  administratively



put it all together in a system orientation by establishing  basic process




groups in the program areas.   There are  a dozen more or less basic proc-




esses or systems with which we must deal and,  of course,  many other less




dominant systems.  Those basic processes are:   agriculture and food;



paper and pulp;  steel and iron including foundries;  aluminum;  copper and




nonferrous metals; electric power;  coal;  petroleum and refining;  chemical




organic and inorganic; glass;  automobiles (mobile sources);  cement;  plas-



tics; synthetics; rubber; textiles;  electroplating;  public waste and




resource recovery; and drinking water.   These process  groups,  to which



we are now going philosophically in EPA  research,  will deal  with all




facets of the process including energy,  resources,  economics,  noise,



air, water, and  solid waste.   They will  also be the recipients of all




technological data and should  therefore  understand the process and




should assist the industry in  improving  the process rather than dealing



negatively with  more sewage disposal  plants or removal equipment.





     You have just had some heart surgery described to you because the



program area is  the heart of EPA and  all the other sections  should sup-



port it.  This orientation already exists to some degree for municipal




waste water and  mobile sources but we stop there;  we do  not  go on to
                                   82

-------
industry and agriculture.  To support these process groups through which



all progress will flow will be such existing functions as:  toxic sub-



stances; resource recovery; pesticides and agricultural chemicals; noise;



water chemistry; fuels; research (applied only); hazardous materials



(radiation); ocean disposal; monitoring; chemical and physical support;



radiation; land use; economic studies; and air cleaning systems.





     It's all there now in EPA but very importantly we have not put it



all together, and you cannot find it.  It is so fragmented we in EPA



really don't know where it is either, but please keep that quiet.   I



would not want that to get around; it's embarrassing.





     The only counter argument in EPA has been from EPA lawyers.   They



say this would allow industry and EPA to get too cozy.  This is a  typical



and proper reaction to those embued with the arms length legal philosophy.



The functional logic and simplicity of such a system organization  should



be its strength and its protection from hanky panky.  But, importantly,



this would improve our technological communication and understanding



greatly.





     When we do progress to a system orientation our decisions will be



more sound and our understandings will be more profound—at that point,



we will truly embark on positive environmental reconstruction rather



than negative restrictive control.






Application of Philosophy to Research





     How can this basic system philosophy be applied to research?   I



repeat that our society cannot afford the economics of end-of-the-pipe



negative environmental control.   I have just suggested a system approach



to the Administration.of Environmental Reconstruction.





     Again in research I believe we must concentrate on the process, but



I  do  not think EPA  or any government agency should direct or execute such
                                   83

-------
process research.  I do not think government can duplicate the talent in




industry nor should it even attempt to do so.





     EPA's function is to augment and stimulate process improvement in




cooperation with industry,  not separate from industry.   Industry on the




other hand should direct and execute process research to create more



energy-efficient, resource-efficient economically sound processes, and



the environment will thereby be served.  And the market will always flow




to the most efficient process.





     We should not direct our thinking to handling waste products.  We




should direct our thinking to byproducts and new products.





     A microcosm of what I  have in mind already exists  on the Houston




ship channel.  As infamous  as this area was in the past, it nevertheless




illustrates that the effluents or emissions of one plant can become the



feedstock for an adjacent process.  This is the concept of  the energy




complex or the industrial complex.  Without this concept even today our



pollution problems and waste of resources would be greater.   The exten-




sion and refinement of this concept in our processes will serve energy,



make better use of our resources,  and serve the environment—all within



economic reason.






Application of Philosophy to Legislation





     The EPA must lead the  way in administration,  in research,  in the




philosophic treatment of our environmental challenges—to show Congress



that the system approach is the way to go in legislation.  At the pres-




ent time we have over-legislated too-detailed  air and water laws, which




do not relate to the earth  or to each other.   This creates  a heavenly



badminton game for bureaucracy, but industry and the public are taking



a beating as the shuttlecock.
                                  84

-------
     I would be so bold as to say the day will come when Congress com-



bines our air, water and land legislation into a single more flexible



system package either through amendments to the present laws or repeal



and replacement of existing laws.








Summary





     In summation, I have suggested my concept of what the future may



bring in philosophy, administration, research and legislation.   I may



have done this with a seeming ingenuous optimism, but I have done so to



stimulate our collective intellectual appetites with a bit of spice and



to present to you my concept of a sound structure on which we can plan



and execute basic and applied research.
                                   85

-------
RESEARCH NEEDS




FIRST VIEWPOINT

-------
                         AN AGENDA FOR RESEARCH

                          Lynton K. Caldwell
                          Indiana University
     The primary need in effective research is to properly understand
the problem about which knowledge is sought.  Failure to satisfy this
need has accounted substantially for the deficiencies of our environmen-
tal research in meeting the needs of public understanding and policy-
development.

     We have attacked specific problems of environmental protection with-
out adequate reference to the general and basic causes of our environ-
mental predicament.  We have launched into research unprepared conceptu-
ally or institutionally to deal with the environmental problem in its
true and full dimensions.  In consequence, we have no basis for discov-
ering what we need to know to bring our general environmental situation
under control.   We cannot be sure that in solving one problem we might
not be inviting others equally unwelcome.

     Our primary research task is therefore to construct a hierarchy of
knowledge that  would relate what we know to what we need to learn,  and
would help us better to understand the multiplex relationships comprising
the total environment.  This structure,  which would never be finished,
could afford a  rational basis for identifying priorities and critical
paths in our research efforts.   It would provide a more reliable means
than we have today for determining how most effectively to deploy our
investments in  environmental research.
                                   89

-------
Identifying Research Needs:   A Complex Task





     The idea of a coherent  structure or hierarchy of knowledge implies




at least three types of research needs that require fulfillment in at-




tacking both the lesser and  larger problems of man's environmental rela-




tionships.  Our particular focus is upon the environmental impacts of



changing resource usages.   But the needs are equally those of environ-




mental research generally.





     Three interrelating types of research needs may be identified.  They




are (1) substantive, (2) functional,  and (3) conceptual.   Substantive



needs comprise the knowledge or understanding required to cope with en-




vironmental problems—in our purview,  with the impact of  changing re-



source usages.  Functional needs refer to the skills, methods, and



facilities required to obtain substantive knowledge and to bring it to



public awareness in forms  suitable for public response.  Conceptual needs




pertain to the comprehension and appreciation of the human environmental



predicament, developing perspective on the total environmental research




task and its complexly interrelated parts.   Only to the extent that each



of these needs is met can  any of them be satisfied.





     Substantive Needs. The knowledge aspect of research needs presents



the following tasks:





     The obvious first task  is the identification of specific information,




either absent or inadequately developed,  concerning the environmental im-



pact of human activities,  including resource usages.  The need is for



answers to the question:  What do we need to know concerning the envi-




ronmental impact of resource usages that we cannot obtain from our infor-




mation base as presently organized?  This need for knowledge is often




formulated as a checklist  of researchable topics.  A recent listing by



the Environmental Studies  Board of the National Research  Council is




appended herewith (Attachment A).  The utility of such lists is limited.
                                  90

-------
They are analogous to shopping lists rather than to program budgets.



They may help to identify environmental problems needing attention,  but



they provide no indication of interrelationships or of relative priori-



ties for research.  Moreover, the shopping list approach provides no



means for discovering what pieces of information, if any, may have been



overlooked.





     The second task of meeting substantive research needs is therefore



the structuring of researchable topics into a hierarchy of knowledge



which is also a grand design or map for research effort.  The difficulty



of this task will be apparent to anyone familiar with the field of en-



vironmental research.  But if successfully accomplished, the rewards



would be commensurate with the effort.  The form required for such a



structure may not be determinable a priori.  A three or four dimensional,



rather than graphic, model might be required.  But, however constructed,



it should reveal linkages, dependencies,  and discontinuities in our



knowledge of the environmental impact of resource usages.





     Because the time dimension must be reflected in any model describ-



ing change, no hierarchy of environmental knowledge can be made final.



Were it to be finalized, it would rapidly become invalid, failing to



reflect the reality of the world in which change is the normal state.



Among the dynamics to be accounted for are changing physical circumstances,



for example, in human populations; in the economy;  in resource availabil-



ity; and in technology among others.  In addition,  new knowledge alters



the configuration of the previous state of knowledge; public attitudes



and political circumstances also change,  with feedback affecting still



other factors.   A valid configuration is therefore necessarily dynamic.





     Yet for the particular point in time at which environmental impacts



are being examined,  it should be possible to determine relative priori-



ties among specific research needs.  And so a structuring of knowledge
                                   91

-------
provide criteria for priorities.   However formulated, these criteria




should reflect:  (1) urgencies,  as estimated by the imminence, magnitude,




intensity, and duration of the impacts; (2)  feasibilities, as determined




by adequacy of existing information,  technique, and social acceptability;



and (3) dependencies among interrelating environmental factors.  From




these data, projected within a time dimension,  it should also be possible



to discern the "critical path" that research must take to solve an envi-




ronmental problem by a specified  future time.





     Functional Needs.  Considerations of the substantive needs of envi-




ronmental research are incomplete until the  means to meet these needs



have also been considered.  Three interrelating aspects of functional



need may be identified:  research capabilities, institutional arrange-




ments, and funding.





     Capabilities include personal and professional skills,  methods,  and



technology required to identify and solve environmental problems.   These



capabilities must necessarily match the complex variety of environmental




relationships.  This is to say that they must be multidisciplinary,  and



yet coherently related through orientation toward common or compatible



research goals—and must be sustainable over time.





     These requirements imply need for an institutional infrastructure




designed to help maintain focus,  orientation, and personnel capabilities.



Built into these arrangements should  be mechanisms for error-detection




and correction, to control quality of output, along with periodic  assess-




ment of the course of the research effort and the adequacy of the  re-



search product in relation to the needs of society and of a more effec-



tive research design.





     There is an obvious need for funding sufficient to sustain the




professional, technological,  and  institutional  capabilities required for



performance of the research tasks.  It is less  apparent, but equally
                                  92

-------
necessary, that the funding commitment be adequate in form and duration



as well as in amount.  It is largely on the critical and controversial



issue of institutional support that efforts to respond to this compre-



hensive interpretation of research needs have been,  and may continue to



be, rejected.





     Conceptual Needs.  The third and most basic research need is for



seeing the environmental predicament of modern man in its full dimensions



Meeting this need implies discovery of the nature of these dimensions,  a



task not yet fully accomplished.  It is neither necessary nor possible



here to describe the circumstances comprising the environmental difficul-



ties of modern man.  But a list of writings that attempt to do so is ap-



pended (Attachment B).





     To the extent that the conceptual need is adequately answered,  it



satisfies three requisites of environmental research.  First, it assists



the framing of a set of general organizing propositions that enables the



researcher to assemble discrete facts into a coherent operational struc-



ture of information.  Second, the conceptual approach affords a rationale



for the potentially greater efficiency of fundamental research as against



the lesser efficiency of short-term expedient problem-solving.  Third,



it reinforces tolerance for the risks associated with creative inquiry



as against the common tendency to insist upon quick, specific, and




politically acceptable results.





     In the practical tasks of environmental research, these three as-



pects—substantive, functional, and conceptual—are  inseparable.  Con-



struction of a hierarchy of knowledge would be a conceptual task, apply-



ing functional means to the organizing and extending of substantive



knowledge through facilitating institutional arrangements.  As this proc-



ess continues, the concepts change with the advancement of knowledge,



and even a substantially stable configuration of knowledge will not be




the same from year to year.




                                   93

-------
Analyzing and Evaluating Substantive Research Needs





     The major impact of human society upon the environmental follows




from its resource usages.  A large part of environmental research is




therefore concerned with how the adverse aspects of this impact can be




alleviated.  Its foci are primarily on environmentally conserving man-




agement of resources (for example, the regulation of strip mining),  and




on changes in consumption that reduce total resource demand or preferen-



tially utilize resources that entail minimal environmental disruption



(for example, sun and wind).   A large body of research pertinent to  en-




vironmental policy is therefore concerned with resources and their uses.



Hence, an important research need is to understand how our knowledge of




materials and resources can be articulated into the general structure of




environmental knowledge.





     This task requires an understanding of the semantics of the re-



source concept.   Contrary to the implications of popular usage,  resources




are not per se physical materials or their properties.  "Resource" is a



techno-economic concept, and materials become resources only when they



are discovered to have a practical utility.  Materials that are truly



inaccessible, or for which no use is known, are not resources in any



practical sense.  No definition of a resource is adequate that,  at least




by implication,  does not indicate the usages of the resource and the




technologies through which these usages are actualized.  A very large



part of the apparatus of modern industrial society (or indeed of any




human society) consists of resource technologies that implement, among




a wide range of functions, those of: (1)  discovering, (2) extracting,



(3) transporting, (4) processing, (5)  fabricating, and (6) reclaiming



or recycling.





     These technical processes imply a cultural and especially an eco-




nomic infrastructure through which society "selects" what resources are




sought; how, when, in what quantities, and at what cost to the environment





                                   94

-------
Consumption patterns are built into this socioeconomic infrastructure,



and environmental research concerned with how resources are used is



inevitably confronted with relevant questions concerning popular values,



preferences, and lifestyles.





     Even a superficial probing of the consumption aspect of resource



uses clarifies the preference of politicians and public officials for



dealing with resource-environment problems in their supply rather than



in their consumption phases.  The history of both energy and environmen-



tal pollution policy illustrates the understandable tendency of govern-



ment to try to accommodate existing consumption patterns rather than to



propose radical alterations in the infrastructure of the economy that



would significantly change resource usages.  For example, in coping with



the impact of the automobile on resources and the environment,  political



choice has opted for temporizing alternatives such as emission controls,



improved combustion efficiency, lower speed limits, and car pools,  as



contrasted to more fundamental measures such as pollution-free fuels,



electrified rapid transit, drastic controls over land development,  in-



dustrial location, and the design and construction of urban facilities.



The reason for the choice should be apparent.  In "making the present



system work better/' the politically dangerous value question is con-



tained; in seeking a better system, a Pandora's box of alternative values




is opened.





     Because resource uses are built into a complex and relatively stable



techno-economic infrastructure, changes in usage seldom occur abruptly.



A decade is perhaps the shortest span of time in which to ascertain or



to effect significant changes.  Studies in the implementation of scien-



tific and technical innovation make doubtful the wisdom of limiting re-



search on the environmental impact of changes in resource usage to inter-



vals of less than a decade.  How far into the future research can, or



should, be projected is perhaps best determined pragmatically.  Different





                                   95

-------
phenomena may proceed on different timetables.   Gross and long-range



tendencies are often easier to verify than are  short-range changes,  sub-




ject to transitory variables of lifestyle,  fashion,  political inter-




ference, and even fluctuations of  the weather.   Technological change




takes longer.  It is difficult to  name any major environment-affecting




technology (for example,  pesticides,  fission  reactors,  or jet propul-




sion) that have not required at least a decade  to develop to the point




of significant environmental impact.





     Because resource uses  are technologically  implemented,  it is hardly




profitable to consider whether environmental  research should focus on




the uses of resources or upon their associated  technologies.   Both must



ultimately be considered although  specific aspects of a total resource



use may be sectored out for study,  provided its total context is kept




in mind.





     Insofar as efforts are made to prevent undesired environmental



impacts from changes in resource usages,  the  following knowledge is



needed.  Basic information  concerns the characteristics of the resource



in question:  (for example,  the properties of the various types of coal).



These data, joined to information  regarding the available implementing



technologies, provides factual data for determining  the amenability  of



the particular resource usage to environment-protection management,  at



what costs, and upon what conditions?  If the incidents of its environ-




mental impact, its degree of hazard,  and  alternative methods and costs




of prevention or amelioration can  be ascertained, the substantive knowl-



edge is at hand upon which  policy  decisions can be based.





     This knowledge, to be  adequate to policy needs,  must provide ans-




wers to the following questions.  First,  how  complete and reliable is



the evidence regarding environmental impacts?  Second,  from what phases




of the resource-use cycle are these impacts incurred?  Third, to what




extent are these impacts:  (1) unavoidable if the resource is used at




                                  96

-------
all;  (2) avoidable through alternative approaches to the purpose to be



served  (for example, through alternative technologies or resource-use



strategies such as cutting down usage to below the threshold of adverse



effects); and  (3) reversible or correctable by physical, technical, eco-



nomic,  and political criteria.  Fourth, what are the second- and third-



order consequences of initial impacts, including synergistic effects,



sequential chain reactions, and the time-space ramifications of these



phenomena.





     A  fifth question, which must be answered for responsible public



officials is:  What are the true and full costs, including the environ-



mental  costs, of meeting a perceived social need through a particular



resource usages?  What alternative tradeoffs exist among resource usages,



and against what criteria are competing values to be identified and



weighted?  This cost assessment, if complete, will include estimated



opportunity costs of alternative resource uses and strategies.  And this



calculus of opportunities need not rest solely on ethical justification,



but equally upon the practical consideration that future possibilities



may materialize much sooner than expected.  The international embargo



and cartelization of oil is a dramatic example of the costs that may be



incurred by optimistically discounting future possibilities.








Requisites of an Adequate Agenda for Research





     The thesis of this paper has been that the nature of modern man's



present environmental circumstance sets the conditions, and hence the



requirements, of research that can answer to our policy needs.  More



than a  shopping list of researchable topics is required to construct



a meaningful agenda for research.  An agenda that fully corresponds to



pur environmental predicament must somehow attempt to account for all of



the significant factors of that predicament.  The outcome of this effort



would be a structure or hierarchy of environmental knowledge that would





                                   97

-------
be larger than the operational agenda of any agency,  but which could




provide orientation and perspective for the research  missions of organi-




zations such as the EPA.





     No attempt is made in this paper to outline such a structuring of




knowledge.  That function is a primary research task, and it is not




necessary to know precisely how to do it to understand that it needs to



be done.  Nor does the probably correct belief that this comprehensive




approach will not be taken argue against its validity.  Mankind has



always been the maker of most of its troubles,  and only in extreme duress



has it faced its options realistically in preference  to acting upon po-



litically or psychologically convenient interpretations of reality.



Hence, there is no compelling reason to believe that  in America,  or




elsewhere, it will effectively seek the kind of knowledge needed for



coping with its environmental problems.





     We may expect that society will continue to seek convenient knowl-



edge, ostensibly of direct and immediate practicality.  So far as this




knowledge goes, it may be reliable, but there are dangers in assuming



that this pragmatic approach to our research needs will enable us to



discover them fully or adequately.   Two hazards of defining research



needs either in response to ad hoc exigencies or by means of extemporan-



eous checklists, are that these approaches not  only provide no means of



ensuring against omission of significant variables from consideration,




but may actually lead toward erraneous conclusions.  No structuring of



environmental knowledge is adequate that does not identify the linkages,




cybernetic mechanisms,  and discontinuities in the structure.  Unless all




significant parameters of the environmental research  task have been




recognized, it will be impossible to identify the critical path leading



from mere factual data to coherent policy alternatives.





     If the foregoing thesis is valid, it then follows that in the con-




struction of a hierarchy of knowledge, problem analysis and definition




                                   98

-------
require major attention.  This is especially so because research toward



environmental problem-solving must proceed even while a more adequate



configuration of knowledge is being created.  Our environmental exigencies



may not wait until our knowledge is adequate to cope with them.  When



there is a necessity to act, action must be taken even if on insufficient



knowledge.  But the objective of a comprehensive structuring of knowledge



is to minimize such necessities.  Thus research toward more adequate con-



ceptualization of environment-resource problems is as important and prac-



tical, and may be less costly, than practical research directed toward



solving specific problems out of context.





     Practical ad hoc research may be applied (perhaps wastefully)  toward



solving the "wrong" problems.  For example, research in automobile-



emission controls may retrospectively appear to have been a poor invest-



ment, considering the eventual and relatively early need for alternatives



to petroleum-powered propulsion.  Moreover, research inadequately concep-



tualized may lead to solutions that create new problems in addition to



those that it presumes to solve.  Pesticide research has frequently led



to such unwanted consequences.  And finally, problem-solving research



projected on narrow conceptual or technical grounds may completely over-



look simpler and less costly solutions to a problem that would become



apparent only through a broader surveillance of the field of relevant




knowledge.





     Any survey of the state of the field will show that our environmen-



tal research needs have largely been defined by ad hoc and shopping-list



approaches.  And it is probable that regardless of their inadequacies,



these will continue to be the guiding approaches.  They are consistent



with the institutional and political realities that produced them,



whereas the comprehensive structuring of knowledge approach is not.
                                   99

-------
Social and Political Constraints on Environmental Research

     Our institutionalized arrangements for environmental research—

academic, industrial, and governmental—hopefully produce at least what

they are capable of producing.   It is hardly surprising that they seldom

produce more than they were designed and funded to produce.   The func-
tional needs of a comprehensive structuring of environmental knowledge—

capabilities, institutional infrastructure,  and funding—remain at pres-

ent largely unprovided.   Nor are they likely to be provided  until the

need for a more adequate concept of our environmental problems is recog-

nized by the American people and their political representatives.

     The prospect for an affirmative public response to this comprehen-

sive interpretation of research needs is not promising.  Constraints

against adoption of this broad  and long-range perspective appear firmly
grounded in the psychological and cultural  assumptions prevailing in (but

certainly not unique to) American society.   These assumptions are seldom

made explicit.  They are instead deducible  from behavior,  and they indi-
cate tendencies and biases in the following pertinent respects:

     •  Insistence on quick and direct answers regardless of the com-
        plexity of a problem (a penchant for "low-budget spectaculars").
     •  Optimistic assessment of natural tendencies (matters to turn out
        better than we expect).

     •  Specialization and reductionist approaches to problem-solving
        (more appropriate to physical than  to environmental  problems).
     •  Temporizing compromise  as against lasting but conflict-producing
        solutions (no one gets  hurt by avoiding trouble).

     •  Preference for symbolic responses over actual remedies that would
        disturb the sociopolitical system (note the tendencies of public
        programs pertaining to  health,  poverty,  crime, and environmental
        pollution).

     But perhaps the greatest constraint on environmental research today

is the strong tendency of governmental and  foundation executives to avoid
                                  100

-------
or to minimize risk.  These officials and their institutions are poorly



equipped for risk assessment in relation to the prospective rewards of



obtaining reliable knowledge of future environmental hazards.  Avoidance



of future substantive risks through acceptance of present deprivations



and controls has little political appeal—especially when the future



hazard is not demonstrably certain and is in any case relatively remote.



It is a near axiom of political life that officials are more readily



punished for mistakes than for inaction.  Better to avoid personal risk



now than to incur public or official displeasure for attempting to fore-



stall social risks in the future.





     The risk-avoidance that tends to characterize official behavior is



also found among researchers.  They tend to select projects for which



funds are available, which promise earlier rather than later or uncertain



payoff, which can be made consistent with specialized disciplinary ori-



entations, and which minimize dependence on other researchers.   Compre-



hensive approaches to environmental problem-solving imply multidiscipli-



nary inputs and coordinative, collaborative team work to a degree that



may obscure the identity (and thus the distinction) of the individual



researcher.  But research as presently instutionalized tends to reward



individuals, not groups.  Individuals receive promotions—not research



teams.





     The risk in opting for the development of a comprehensive structure



of environmental knowledge is the risk of sponsoring efforts that are



novel, that require changes in values and assumptions, that cannot prom-



ise early or clearly defined returns.  Even though a research effort of



the kind here indicated would absorb only a small part of the money spent



on environmental research,  and would reinforce rather than compete with



productive work in progress,  few are the public officials that may be



expected to recommend it and few are the legislators that would respond
                                   101

-------
favorably to a proposition so heavy on theory and so light on politically




usable results.





     It therefore follows that the investment needed to meet the primary




environmental research needs of the nation will not be made.  It does




not further follow that environmental knowledge will not be advanced.



Useful and important work will be done.   But in the long run more money




will have been spent,  less useful knowledge will have been acquired,  and




fewer environmental and resource policy  errors avoided than would be



probable had more support been given to  the more fundamental and contin-




uing need for an adequate structure of environmental knowledge.   Never-



theless the case for a better approach should be presented,  even though



the probabilities of its early acceptance are slight.
                                  102

-------
                             Attachment A





                  CRITICAL ISSUES IN NATURAL RESOURCES
Agriculture
     World Food - U.S. production, technology transfer to  foreign nations




     Renewable Resources - as substitutes for nonrenewable




     Fertilizer - production from other sources than natural  gas


                  biological fixation of N_
                                          &



     Runoff pollution by chemicals and fertilizer




     Food losses
Air Pollution
     Health basis for standards, epidemiology



     Automotive emissions, energy relationship



     Sulfur oxides and sulfates problems



     Acid rain



     Atmospheric chemistry and transport



     Ozone layer





Atomic Energy





     Breeder reactor



     Nuclear risks



     Role of nuclear in energy mix



     Uranium reserves



     Radioactive waste disposal





Chemicals in the Environment





     Asbestos



     Chlorofluorocarbons
                                  103

-------
     Pesticides
     Toxic substances regulation

     Biogeochemical cycles
Coal
     Increased mining

     Strip mining,  rehabilitation

     Slurry pipelines

     Coal conversion processes

Coastal Zone

     OCS resources

     On-shore impacts

     Estuaries

Ecology and Ecosystem Analysis

     Fragile ecosystems

     Managed ecosystems

     Ecology as a predictive science

Electric Power

     Fuel sources

     Thermal pollution
Energy
     Better numbers on world oil and gas reserves

     Demand modification and conservation - what is possible and how
     much does it help

     Coal conversion problems

     Increased coal production

     Hot rock geothermal
                                   104

-------
EPA - $5 Million Program

     Decision-making with uncertainty

     Comprehensive environmental management, cross-media pollution
     considerations

     ORD effectivenesss

Fish and Wildlife

     Predator control - evaluation of alternative strategies

International

     SCOPE - ICSU projects

     UNEP liaison

     Bilateral projects

     Environmental protection requirements as a part of AID

Institutional Problems

     Environmental Impact Statement quality and effectiveness

     The need for an Environmental Analysis Institute

     Obtaining and using proprietary information in public policy
     deliberations

Land Use

     Scientific basis for land use planning

     Local versus federal control issue

     Carrying capacity concept

     Land quality protection equivalent to AQ and WQ

     Patterns of settlement

Marine Affairs

     Fisheries management

     Mineral resources recovery

     Ocean as a sink, dumping, rivers, out falls, etc.
                                 105

-------
     Marine mammal protection



     Deep water ports
Minerals





     Forecasting reserves,  demand,  and possible shortages




     Dependence on foreign sources



     Mobilization of minor elements





Motor Vehicles





     Emissions to ambient relationship




     Unregulated emission species



     Pollution control versus energy requirement





Oil and Gas





     Oil spills



     LNG transport





Pesticides





     Comprehensive decision making



     Eradication




     Integrated pest management
R&D
     EPA - Office of Research and Development



     Interagency coordination
Solid Waste
     Containers



     Recycling




     Incineration




     Tailings
                                   106

-------
Water Pollution





     NCWQ report



     Effluent change concept



     Dredging



     Trace organics



     Water reuse



     Nonpoint sources





Weather and Climate





     Weather modification



     Climate and agriculture



     Ozone layer.
                                  107

-------
                             Attachment B

               REFERENCES ON ENVIRONMENTAL DIFFICULTIES
     Mesarovic, Mihajlo, and Eduard Pestel,  Mankind at the Turning  Point:
The Second Report to the Club of Rome.  New York:   Dutton, 1974.

     Meadows, Donella, Dennis Meadows et al.,  The  Limits to Growth:  A
Report for the Club of Rome's Project on the Predicament of Mankind.
New York:  Universe Books, Inc., 1974.

     Watt, Kenneth E. F., The Titanic Effect.   New York:   Dutton, 1974,
268.

     Platt, John R. , Perception and Change.   Ann Arbor:   University of
Michigan Press, 1970, 178.

     Heilbroner, Robert, An Inquiry into the Human Prospect.   New York:
W. W. Norton, 1974, 150.

     Ward, Barbara and Rene Dubos,  eds.   Only One  Earth.   New York:
Norton, 1972.
                                  109

-------
                 REVIEW OF THE PAPER BY L.  K.  CALDWELL

                            Stanley A. Cain
                 University of California,  Santa Cruz
     Professor Caldwell has told us at the start that environmental  re-

search has fallen short.  He is blunt about it.   Having failed to  under-

stand the problem about which knowledge is sought,  we have launched  into

isolated studies without being aware of the true and full dimensions of

our environmental dilemmas.  However clever technologically,  we have

been unprepared conceptually and institutionally to deal with environ-

mental problems and bring them under control.   I accept his indictment

as being generally true.

     In comparison with the life sciences, the physical sciences and

their derived technologies have an enviable exactness.   The life sciences

lack this except when they can use the knowledge and methods  of the

physical sciences.  By then we are not dealing with life but  with  the

substratum through which life phenomena are manifested.  In either case,

Caldwell says that we cannot be sure that in getting data on  one problem

we might not be inviting others equally unwelcome in terms of environ-

mental quality.

     There is no hint from him that we should wish any less support  for

the natural sciences.  It is, rather, that our not fully understanding

the problems about which knowledge is sought,  the branches of science

are not coordinated,  especially in relation to the wider understandings,

institutions, and methodologies of the social sciences.  Political sci-

ence,  economics, and  sociology are an embarrassment.  People do not behave

like physical particles and reactions; they are unpredictable and  seem

to do  as they please.

                                  Ill

-------
     In the first paragraph he stresses the deficiencies of environmen-




tal research in meeting the needs of public understanding and policy




development.  He does not charge that the natural sciences are more at




fault than the social sciences in producing environmental dilemmas.




Lacking a holistic philosophy, we have been unable to anticipate the




problems that are produced by partial solutions which,  often, do not in



fact solve an environmental problem or, in doing so,  produce others.  He




states his thesis in these words:   Our primary task is  to construct a




hierarchy of knowledge that would relate what we know to what we need



to learn, and would help us better to understand the  multiplex relation-




ships comprising the total environment.





     I like Caldwell's philosophy and his' wisdom so much that I would be



happier had he not used the word "hierarchy" which indicates a linear



order of authority as from pope to parish priest or from king to com-



moner.  However, it turns out that he means that only multidimensional



models will serve well for thinking about and working on environmental




problems.  He certainly does not mean that we should  establish a linear




list of things to do but,  rather,  that we contemplate all kinds of  knowl-



edge that we need if we are to escape from our environmental predicaments



and stop producing nonsolutions.  A nonsolution,  of course, consists of



learning about a thing, condition, or process and then  putting the  re-




sults into practice with scarcely a thought for the consequences.   When




a problem is isolated to be attacked we cannot afford any longer to




think of it as existing in isolation.   Its isolation  is of our creation,




for the purpose of studying one variable at a time.  The condition  or




process, whatever it may be, will most likely have a  family of causes and



any changes that result from research will likely have  a complex of con-




sequences.  The environment cannot be dealt with satisfactorily by  linear




thinking—an improvement over compartmentalized thinking—nor can it be



usefully understood out of context.
                                  112

-------
     Being a political scientist, and a broadly based and wise one at



that, he immediately emphasizes in his paper the principal deficiency



in environmental research, the failure to relate the environmental ef-



forts of scientists and technologists to the needs of public understand-



ing and policy development.  The problems arising from the progressive



loss of environmental quality cannot be solved by the sciences alone,



nor by the familiar engineering technologies that apply them, however



clever they may be, but require the full panoply of the social sciences.



I would add my belief that solutions of environmental problems also re-



quire participation of the humanities, the communication fields,  and a



dedication of our institutions of education at all levels.





     Caldwell organizes his thoughts.  For example, he says that  research



needs fall into three interrelated categories.  First are substantive



needs for knowledge to cope with a problem.  Second are the functional



needs for skills, methods, institutional arrangements and facilities, and



funding.  Third are the conceptual needs to see environmental problems



whole, not failing to comprehend that a thing, condition, or process is



likely a mere link in a complex situation.  These three sets of research



needs have to be met if the objective of anticipating environmental con-



sequences of our actions are to be anticipated, especially as changing



uses of resources arise.





     The record is not one to make us sanguine about the future.   We have



not anticipated the environmental consequences of our actions, and we



will do better in the future as resource usages change only if research



is organized so as to deal with all of the cells and linkages of  the



complex systems rather than with things, conditions, and processes one



at a time.   The encouraging point is this:  the core of the wisdom that




has called forth this conference.
                                  113

-------
     Caldwell also recognizes that no such framework for the guidance of

research is a template of enduring usefulness.   It is a device for keep-

ing us humble and reminding us that change is inevitable.  As he says,

new knowledge alters the configuration of the previous state of knowledge.

There will be no simplistic and final solutions.   This position is not

defeatist.  On the contrary,  it is the only position that promises some

confidence that life and environment can be satisfactory.
    f
     He distinguishes between natural resources in being and those that

are latent or potential.  He says also that it  is of little use to list

known resources in order of importance except,  perhaps,  as to known and

demonstrated uses at the present.  This causes  him to conclude that it

is profitless to do research only on existing resource-use patterns.

This would be little more than fine-tuning the  wrong engine.  He ex-

presses the point more elegantly when he says "the tendency of govern-

ment is to try to accommodate consumption patterns rather than to pro-

pose radical alteration in the infrastructure of  the economy that would

significantly change resource usages."

     For a variety of reasons,  the techno-economic infrastructure is not

geared for rapid change.  It is too complicated to do so.  For every

resource there exists a sequence of steps between the raw material, con-

dition, or natural process in nature and its practical usage.  Every

link in a sequence and every chain that ends in a different usage has its

technological requirements,  capital requirements,  skilled personnel,  mar-

kets and merchandizing system,  and profit for some.   Each step may have

its own environmental impacts and there is no overall responsibility for

the system.  There has been no mechanism for pinpointing the sources and

causes of undesirable environmental consequences,  and hence no central-

ized responsibility until recently a start has  been made at the federal

level with the EPA.
                                  114

-------
     It is not unfair, I think, nor unappreciative to say that success



awaits a parallel responsibility in all pertinent governmental agencies



and all private organizations with involvement.   As Caldwell says,  en-



vironmental impacts occur at every step, not just with the disposal of



the ultimate waste products.  This being true,  policy requires reliable



and specific information concerning impacts at  every stage.   Which  im-



pacts are unavoidable, granted the nature of the resource and the tech-



nology of extracting it from nature?  Which impacts can be ameliorated



or removed with a different technology?  Similar questions can be asked



at each step.  Which impacts set off a chain of impacts?  What is the



duration of the impact?  How wide is the area affected?  What are the



true and full costs?  Who shall bear the costs?  How shall those  who



suffer get redress?





     I do not find Caldwell sanguine about the  outcome even though  there



is a growing awareness of the loss of environmental quality.  He  says



that mankind has always been the maker of most  of its troubles, and only



in extreme duress has it faced its options realistically in preference



to acting upon politically or psychologically convenient interpretations



of reality.  Hence there is no compelling reason to believe that  in



America, or elsewhere, it will effectively seek the kind of knowledge



needed for coping with its environmental problems.





     There are several reasons for this pessimism.  We continue to  seek



convenient knowledge of direct and immediate practicality.  This  approach



provides no means of ensuring against leaving out significant variables.



I would impose an interpretation of my own at this point by ascribing



the prevailing attitude to a general lack of understanding of the intri-



cate interconnectedness of life and environment.  We find more holism  in



a good mystery novel than in the usual textbook.  The further along one




moves in the educational system, the more compartmentalized information



gets.  The tendency is to atomize information rather than to synthesize






                                   115

-------
it except in specialized fields of learning.   On the other hand, religion




and philosphy tend not to deal with the same facts in an objective way



that confront the scientist,  the technolgist,  the economist, the politi-




cian, and all the rest v/ho run our world for six days a week at least.




It is easy enough to blame someone for an undesirable environmental im-




pact.  When the causes are shared by everyone,  when the system is at




fault, the victims are the culprits.





     Quite properly, Caldwell calls for a structuring of knowledge that




will show the linkages and the feedbacks and loops.   We need to try to




see our problems whole.  We are not used to this and it is easier to



blame the government:   administrators,  politicians,  or both, forgetting




that vie are the government when we make use of  our citizenship.  It is




easier to blame industry, bankers,  lawyers, merchants,  labor,  farmers,




or for that matter the Arabs, the Russians, and the people downtown or



in the suburbs.  There is enough blame to go  around.  Scientists and



engineers get some of it, and the economists, political scientists,



sociologists, psychologists,  and the planners,  too,  although they are



more of an enigma.





     This situation is uncomfortable but not  all that bad because the




people are grasping collectively,  if not as individuals,  that our lives



are interrelated even though we are not organized to deal with the in-



terrelations.  Caldwell has said or implied this, although more elegantly




than I have, in his insistence that we have to  learn to think and act in




relation to the system with all of its frustrating linkages, cybernetic



mechanisms, and discontinuities.





     I do not find Professor Caldwell optimistic.  In his paper I find



such statements as these:
                                  116

-------
     •  The prospect for an affirmative public response to this compre-
        hensive interpretation of research needs is not promising.

     •  Perhaps the greatest constraint on environmental research today
        is the strong tendency of governmental and foundation executives
        to avoid or minimize risk.

     •  The risk-avoidance that tends to characterize official behavior
        is also found among researchers.

     •  The investment needed to meet the primary environmental research
        needs of the nation will not be made.

     •  Mankind has always been the maker of most of its troubles,  and
        only in extreme duress has it faced its options reaslistically
        in preference to acting upon politically or psychologically
        convenient interpretations of reality.  Hence there is no com-
        pelling reason to believe that in America, or elsewhere,  it will
        effectively seek the kind of knowledge needed for coping with
        its environmental problems.

     An old Irish saying is that we are going to hell in a wheelbarrow.

Today the figure of speech might be anyone of a number of vehicles  that

travel at supersonic speeds.

     I think that Professor Caldwell is somewhat carried away by his

theme.  But he is at this conference telling it like it is, a conference

sponsored by a federal agency with a host that is famous for its share

of atomized research.

     The holistic science of ecology is well and working.  Earth Week

was not a fiasco for innumerable young persons.  Resources for the

Future is staffed by economists who are alert to and concerned about

environmental problems and rewriting a good deal of economics.  There

are physicists and chemists doing homely but valuable work adapting

waste disposal systems,  energy-capture, and water-conserving devices to

the small landowner and his home.  Even some agricultural experiment

stations are showing tolerance for organic farming and a growing unease

about pesticides and inorganic fertilizers.  Those who weep for wildlife

arrived instinctively where the genepool geneticists are now coming.
                                  117

-------
The young people who have opted out are returning to colleges and uni-




versities and will help when they see that there is a chance for sensible



changes in resource usage and environmental protection.   Many are study-




ing natural history, ecology,  the earth sciences,  and land-use planning,




looking to careers in resources management.  This  conference will be



appreciated by them and many others.
                                  118

-------
 RESEARCH NEEDS




SECOND VIEWPOINT

-------
           THE DESIRABILITY OF AN INTERDISCIPLINARY APPROACH
           TO RESEARCH OX THE ANTICIPATION OF ENVIRONMENTAL
                 IMPACTS OF CHANGES IN RESOURCE USAGE

                            Robert C. North
                          Stanford University
The Compartmentalization of Knowledge

     Until recently, a major constraint affecting environmental research
and policy-making has emerged from the fact that human knowledge has
tended to be compartmentalized among many distinct disciplines—physics,
chemistry, geology;  engineering, biology, economics, psychology, manage-
ment, political science, law, and so forth—whereas reality involves the
intense interaction of variables that cut across these and other discip-
lines.  Especially in the social sciences, each discipline has been in-
clined to approach the study of environmental problems in terms of its
own partial view, specialized conceptual framework, vocabulary, data,
and method of analysis.  As a consequence, many experts tend to wear
professional blinders, and policymaking agencies—to say nothing of the
general public—are bombarded with unrelated or conflicting viewpoints
which often confuse, rather than elucidate, the basic issues.

     Resource usage and consequent environmental impacts are functions
of the activities of human beings organized, on various societal levels,
into complex social  systems.  Without human beings and their social sys-
tems no such usages  and impacts would take place. It is almost axiomatic,
therefore, that problems of resource usage and environmental impacts are
virtually inseparable from the structure and functioning of social sys-
tems ranging from the community and private firm to the nation and even

the world.
                                   121

-------
     Because of intense interactivity among critical variables and be-

cause of complex social, economic, and political—as well as technologi-

cal—feedback arrangements,  we are dealing with a congeries of problems

that are extremely difficult for analyst and policymaker alike to manage

successfully or even properly understand.  To ancipate the environmental

impacts of changing resource usage over any sustained period of time, it

is necessary at the very minimum:   (1) to obtain some notion of the ef-

fects of such impacts upon the social systems that produce them and

(2) even beyond that, to identify at least some of the consequences for

subsequent usage change of any social, economic, or political alterations

that take place as a consequence of previous usage change (as well as

usage change resulting from other factors).


The Importance of Population-Resource-Technology Variables

     Of the many variables that seem pertinent to an understanding of

environmental problems, there are three--population, resources,  and

technology—that are intensely interactive and at the same time funda-

mental to enlightened domestic and foreign policy.*  Obviously,  a con-

siderable number of other important variables can be derived from these

three.

     Once set forth, the simple logic of various population-resource-

technology combinations is difficult to ignore.   Human beings are criti-

cally dependent on their physical  environments.   As biological organisms,

they have certain basic needs,  especially food,  water,  air and some

amount of territory.  The larger a given population, the greater will

be the demands for these basic resources.
*Nazli Choucri and Robert C.  North,  Nations  in Conflict:   National Growth
 and International Violence (San Francisco,  W.  H.  Freeman, Co.,  1975).
                                  122

-------
      In  their  search  for resources,  human beings  depend  upon  technology—

 the  application of  knowledge  and  skills.   Changes in  resource usage are

 normally an  indicator of changes  in  technology.   Changes in technology

 and  resource usage, in turn,  bring about  alterations  in  both  the natural

 and  the  social environments.   By  making new  resources available and

 yielding new uses for old  resources,  advances  in  technology often lead

 to greater concentration of population.   But such advances in technology
 create their own demands for  resources with  the result that the margins

 of energy surplus that are required  for stability and sustained growth
 tend to  be variable.

      The more advanced the level  of  technology in a society,  the greater
 will be  the  kinds and quantities  of  resources needed by  a society to

 sustain  that technology  and advance  it further.   Technologies normally
 require  three types of resources  to maintain them:  biological and

 mechanical energy;  structural  materials for  tools, machines, plants and

 other equipment; and  those resources  such as food, textiles, metals and

 so forth  that are transported, transformed and distributed for human use.

     At  least some advances in technology yield greater  economies in the

 transfer and utilization of primary energy  and other resources,  that  is,

 greater utility of output  is achieved for each unit of resource input.'''

Over the great sweep of human pre-history and history, however,  each

major development in technology has tended to encourage a proliferation

of applications and to catalyze innumerable other technological enter-

prices and uses—each  requiring resources for structure  (machines,  tools,
*Hans Thirring,  Energy for Man:   Windmills to Nuclear Power (Bloomington:
 Indiana University Press, 1958), p.  21.
tCf.  T.  K.  Derry and T.  I. Williams,  A Short History of Technology (Ox-
 ford:   The Clarendon Press,  1960),  pp.  319-21.

                                  123

-------
plant equipment),  for fuel (wood,  coal,  oil)  or for processing (wool,




cotton, iron ore,  raw rubber and so forth).





     Advances in technology tend also to increase the amount and the




range of what people think they need above and beyond such basic neces-




sities as food,  water,  air and minimal living space.  Rising standards




of living mean massive growth in consumption  to the point where an aver-



age citizen of the United States uses more than a thousand times as much




energy per year as the average Burundian or Nepalese.  As technologies



advance, moreover, even the procurement  and distribution of these rela-




tively simple necessities tend to  involve larger and larger networks of



instrumentalities.  Ancient people acquired water by dipping into the




nearest spring,  river or lake.  But today their descendants in a high-



rise apartment depend upon hierarchies of complex instrumenalities—all



requiring energy and other resources—when they draw the same amount



of water from the tap of their thirtieth floor apartments.  These con-



siderations mean that in terms of  environmental impact an increase of



the population of a highly industrialized society by one person may be




equivalent to a population increase of up to  a thousand in an under-



developed society.







Social, Economic and Political Institutions on Coping Mechanisms





     Both the numbers of people and the  characteristics of the prevail-




ing technology influence the way a society organizes itself.  Any strong




environmental feature or any peculiarity of population, technology on




availability of resources that stimulates recurrent behavior, and espe-



cially perseverant interactions among numbers of people, influences a




society's customs, laws, institutions, and other domestic structures.




And, in turn, these customs, laws, institutions and other structures



influence, shape and constrain behavior, control resource distributions




and regulate relations established in part,  at least, by divisions of
                                  124

-------
labor.   As population increases, the percentage of the population in

cities tends to increase, and this tendency affects almost every aspect
of life."1"

     Technological development has tended not only to increase the range

and amount of resources available to a society, but to influence indi-

vidual and social behavior as well.  Indeed, governmental structures on

all levels may be viewed as having emerged, in part, as mechanisms where-

by societies at various levels of development have sought to cope with

the physical environment, oversee the acquisition, transformation and

distribution of resources, and relate to other societies.  Major altera-

tions in technology such as the agricultural revolution have contributed

to major alterations in the ways various societies have governed them-
selves domestically and related to each other externally.  To the extent

that parts of the world may already be embarked on another such revolu-

tion—perhaps an electronic and massive energy transformation revolution-

the impact of such changes in social, economic and political structures

becomes as critical as societal influences upon the relationships of
population, resources and technology.

     Particular technologies require particular divisions of labor which

often become institutionalized,  affecting how people live,  and often pro-

viding the structure for economic,  social and political hierarchies.

Even the form of government will be affected by the size and density of

the population and by the technology and the work people do.   Complex
*See Karl  A.  Wittfogel,  Oriental Despotism:   A Comparative Study  of  Total
 Power (New Haven:   Yale University Press,  1959).
tLewis Mumford  in William L.  Thomas,  Jr.  (ed.)  Man's  Role in Changing the
 Face of the  Earth.   Vol.  I  (Chicago:   The  University of Chicago  Press,
 1956), p.  394;  cf.  Aristotle in Benjamin Jowett,  trans.  The Politics of
 Aristotle (Oxford:   The Clarendon Press, 1885), Vol. I, p.  43.
                                  125

-------
feedback effects operate from population,  resources,  and technology to




economics and politics,  and from economics and politics, culture and




society back to these more aggregate and basic "master" variables.  Any




marked or significant changes in either the master or the institutional




variables will have reverberating effects throughout  the system as a




whole.  To a large degree, the domestic and internal  politics of a




society, as well as its  economics,  will thus depend on its prevailing



technology, on population-resource-technology ratios  and trends, on who




controls the society's primary energy and other resources (and by what



means), and on its budgetary distributions and other  major allocations.





     The entire sweep of human pre-history and history has been charac-




terized by larger populations,  by more advanced technologies, by the



ability to employ larger amounts of energy and other  resources for human




purposes and by demands  for greater quantities and wider ranges of goods



and services.  Increasingly over time,  demands for energy and other re-



sources have escalated because of these overall growth trends.  This



means that, whereas in the past the growth of a given society or civil-



ization began eventually to press against local or regional resource




limitations, the constraints of the future are likely to have worldwide



implications.





     Such phenomena as resource depletion and environmental pollution




are as old as the human  species.  During the eras of  human pre-history,




scattered bands and tribes normally solved these problems by moving into




new territory.  But as towns and cities were established and as sedentary




populations grew, communities and sometimes whole civilizations were af-



fected by pollution and  depletion problems.   The outcomes were varied.




In some instances, the nuclear society expanded—peacefully or by con-



quest—into fresh territories.   In other instances, the development of




a new technology, such as large scale irrigation or commerce by land



or sea, enabled the society to continue growing.  In  still other cases,





                                  126

-------
the depletion of the soil or other resources (often combined with pollu-



tion in various forms) led to stagnation or even the collapse of a whole



society or civilization.  Historically, however, it has also been char-



acteristic of great societies and even of whole civilizations that—after



generations of demographic, technological and economic growth—the spi-



ralling demands of the people have exceeded the depleted supply of readily



available resources and the technological capacity for obtaining new re-



sources or for finding new uses for the old resources.





     Depletion does not usually mean that a source is exhausted, but



rather that the more readily available, the more concentrated,  the richer



or the higher quality deposits have been used up.   Monetary costs will



be a critical factor in determining whether a given community or society



exploits resources that are near at hand or reaches out beyond its own



borders to obtain them by one means or another elsewhere.   As the more



readily available resources are depleted, is it more economical to de-



velop new capabilities for exploiting harder-to-get substitutable dom-



estic materials, or to acquire them through foreign trade  or conquest?



In the past,  many countries with sufficient naval  or military capabili-



ties acquired overseas colonies or protectorates in order  to ensure



access to critical resources.  These tendencies often shaped the expec-



tations, dispositions and policies of new nations  emerging from old



colonial areas.





     In the longer run, the cost of acquiring resources overseas has



often become prohibitive to a previously dominant  society—either in



terms of purchase and transportation costs or in political or defense



costs,  casualties suffered by expeditionary or occupation  forces and the



like.  Under such circumstances political, commercial or industrial




leaders of the dominant society sometimes succeeded in developing new



technologies  for acquiring the hard-to-get domestic resources more




cheaply or for utilizing other resources in new ways.





                                  127

-------
     The demands of a society must be combined with suitable capabili-

ties if effective activity is to be generated and sustained.  When de-
mands are unmet and existing capabilities are insufficient to satisfy
them, new capabilities may have to be developed.  But a society can de-
velop particular capabilities only if it possesses or acquires the tech-
nology and resources necessary for creating them.  Much can thus be in-
ferred about the probable behavior of a society according to the pattern
of its demands and capabilities, including the state of its technology.
In this connection, many societies seem to fall roughly into one of the
following categories:
           Low Technology
     High Technology
      High population
      Limited access to resources
        (China , 1900)

      Low population
      Limited access to resources
        (Afghanistan)

      Low population
      Favorable access to resources
        (Saudi Arabia)
High population
Limited access to resources
  (Japan, 1930s)

Low population
Favorable access to resources
  (Sweden)

High population
Favorable access to resources
 (United States—at least
  until recently)
     Each one of these six general types of countries faces its own
particular problems.   A strong new trend in any one of the three "master"

variables—whether of growth or decline—has implications for the other

two variables, for the society as a whole,  and for its relations with
other societies.

     Current strains  on political, social and economic systems are al-

ready very high.  Even more rapid changes are likely to take place in

the immediate future.  The forms and practices of government will

                                  128

-------
undoubtedly be called upon  to meet rising demands and the many problems

associated with the acquisition, transformation and distribution of criti-

cal resources.  Until now, however, very little systematic research has

been done on the long-range effects of population, technology and access

to resources on values, custom, law, domestic institutions,  demands,

capabilities and forms and procedures of government,  and whatever is

formulated about such relationships must be accepted as largely hypo-

thetical, if not speculative.


Some Difficulties Inherent in the Analysis and Regulation of Social
Systems

     Among many social scientists there is a growing consensus that rela-

tively little is understood about how large and complex social systems—

including large cities, large public enterprises and large states and

empires—really work.  All too often, the intuitively obvious outcome

of a policy or action does not occur.  And all too often, the program

that is undertaken to solve a problem has a reverse effect or, in solving

one difficulty, creates or exacerbates another.

     There are numerous reasons why social systems are difficult to ana-

lyze, understand, and control.  To begin with, all social systems exhibit

equifinality,  that is, similar "lines" or "paths" or sequences of behavior

often lead to  different outcomes, and similar outcomes are often reached

by different "paths" or by the same antecedents in different sequence.

The consequence is that system structure in many instances may be more

important than system state,  i.e., the nature of interrelationships among

elements may be "more critical than the precision of the input data.

Yet analysts and decision-makers alike may be inclined out of precedence

and habit to look at "input"  rather than "structure."  Also, many complex

social  systems tend to be "stable in response to most changes in input,

yet exhibit catastrophic changes in the face of a few gradual alterations

in input."  And there are often long time lags in the accommodation of

                                   129

-------
systems to change-a tendency that is likely to encourage false causal

inferences among both analysts and policy makers.   The consequence is

that the behavioral outcomes of complex systems often appear all the
                                    *
more unexpected or counterintuitive.

     There are other reasons why scholars, planners,  managers and states-

men, as well as the public at large,  may misunderstand and misinterpret

the nature and behavior of large and complex social systems.  "it is my
basic theme," wrote Jay W. Forrester a number of years back, "that the
human mind is not adapted to interpreting how social  systems behave.  Our
social systems belong to the class called multiloop,  nonlinear feedback
systems."f  Such systems normally involve hierarchies within hierarchies

of  complicated and often influential feedback loops involving social,

economic, political, technological and resource variables.

     In the long course of human evolution it has not been necessary for

people, until very recent historical times, to understand these systems—
or  to acquire enlightened control over them.  Because of their limited
population  size and technological capacities and because of the buffering
effect of geographical obstacles and sheer distance,  societies in the

past could  do only limited and localized damage to the natural environ-
ment and  to mankind as a whole.  Civilizations could "muddle through
 for centuries at a time without intolerable damage to the earth or  to
 the human race.  Therefore,  experience may not have provided us with  the
constructs  required to interpret properly the dynamic social and politi-
 cal behavior of  the  systems  of which we  are not critical parts.  As a
 *Harold A.  Linston,  "Planning:  Toy  or Tool?" JEEE  Spectrum (April  1974)
  p.  44.
 tJay Forrester,  "Counterintuitive  Behavior of Social  Systems,"  ZPG
  National Reporter (June 1971).

                                   130

-------
consequence,  a society may suffer "a growing sense of futility" as it

repeatedly attacks deficiencies which the symptoms," in fact,  "continue
to worsen."

     It appears to be characteristic of many contemporary social systems

that they have a relatively few sensitive influence points through which

the behavior of the system can be changed.  Frequently,  such influence

points are not located where analysts, planners,  managers or politicians

expect them to be.  Furthermore, if a sensitive point has been identified

in a location where influence can be exerted, the probabilities often

are that a person "guided by intuition and judgment will alter the sys-

tem in the wrong direction."t  In fact, a social system may draw our

attention to the very points at which an attempt to intervene will fail.

"When we look, we discover that the social system presents us with an

apparent cause that is plausible according to what we have learned from

simple systems.  But this apparent cause may be a coincident occurrence

that, like the trouble symptom itself, is being produced by the feedback-
                                 Tr j.
loop dynamics of a larger system. +

     Whatever its advantages, every course of action also involves costs

which someone must bear.   There is no fully satisfactory way of having

one's cake and eating it, too.  Critical questions relate to how the

benefits and  costs are distributed within the society as a course of

action is undertaken.  Also,  in any hierarchy of systems, there is often

an inherent conflict between the best interests and goals of a subsystem

and the best  interests and goals of the broader system.   The interests

will tend to  conflict with worldwide human interests, the immediate
*Ibid.
tlbid.
*Ibid.
                                  131

-------
interests of the unemployed may run counter to the control of overall

inflation, the conservation of a local environment may be at odds with

a nation-wide demand for oil,  and so forth.  Yet all these interests and

goals may be legitimate and "just" from one or another perspective.*

     These tendencies are exercerbated by the conflicts that often exist

between short-term interests and long-term interests.   The solution of

this year's economic problem may be achieved at a cost to the environ-

ment that will not be fully exacted until ten or twenty years hence.

Pressures for a short-run advantage may lead to a minimizing of the

longer-term cost.   It is difficult for a living populace to deny itself

in the interest of generations that are not yet born.

     In some situations economic growth seems to present another paradox

or decision-making dilemma.  Unless a nation's production increases year

by year,  the economy may be depressed.   Historically,  those societies

that have ceased to grow economically and technologically have often

declined  or been overrun by their enemies.   On the other hand, unlimited

growth over an extended period may contribute to resource scarcities,

pollution, urban stagnation,  trade imbalances, international conflicts

on various levels  and outright war.   And seemingly no  society can grow

forever.

     Many difficult contradictions emerge from the fact that populations,

resources and technology are differentially distributed among the coun-

tries of  the world.  Strong growth in a country's economy and production

capacity  may increase competition with  other countries for resources,

markets and the strategic advantages considered necessary for securing

trade routes.  While seeking to strengthen its own position, each country
*Ibid.
tlbid.

                                  132

-------
tends to validate the competitive anxieties of its rivals.  As resources



are depleted or markets flooded, each of the countries is likely to re-



double its efforts, thus exercerbating demands and possibilities for



conflict.





     In recent years this paradox has developed new and complicated



dimensions.  Before World War II, and to some extent thereafter; the



industrialized countries of the world were able to obtain protected



access to resources and markets through the acquisition of colonies, and



the acquisition of colonial territory is no longer as feasible.  The



social, economic, political and military penetration of these so-called



underdeveloped countries has accordingly become more sophisticated and



more critical—with the realization, by strong and weak societies alike,



of the need for secure access to energy and other resources in a world



of scarcities.  Increasingly, also, a number of weaker countries are



beginning to perceive possibilities for increasing their power and in-



fluence by vigorously controlling and regulating access to their domestic



resources by the industrialized countries.  This possibility adds to



their potential influence in world monetary affairs,  in conferences



dealing with sea bed resources, in debates and critical voting proce-



dures of the United Nations General Assembly, and in the proceedings of




other international agencies.





     Our understanding of social systems and how they work is impeded



by the complicated ways in which actions often relate to each other.



Actions are so commonplace in human affairs that we often take them for



granted,  scarcely bothering to define what they are.   In fact, what we



often identify as a single action turns out to be a complexity of actions



within actions within actions, so that what is referred to as the act or



action is only that aspect which creates the most immediate impact upon



the human senses,  or its amounts to a conceptual shorthand for a very
                                  133

-------
complicated phenomenon such as the overall effort to  generate a 'green

revolution" in South Asia.

     For an actor A to do something to actor B (or to the general envi-

ronment C) , he—A—may have to do something else, "not subsequently,  but

in order to initiate, continue or complete his action."  The activities

of an individual can thus become extremely complicated.  Clearly the

decision of state, community,  firm, nation state or other large and com-
plex social system is even more complicated than the activity of a single
individual.  In any inclusive action or activity the smaller, component

action units may be viewed as "molecular" and the larger ones as "molar."*
The molar units are thus composed of molecular units.  This suggests  that

"we are trying to describe a process that is organized on several differ-
            j.
ent levels."

     With respect to organizational as well as individual behavior, a

molar activity may have consequences as a molar unit which are not the
same as the consequences of the molecular units it includes.*  In view
of these  complexities—and the potential for "side-effects" and other
unanticipated and unwanted consequences—it is unfortunate that much

analysis  and decision-making focuses upon the intended outcome of the

"molar" activity, but not upon the possible effects of the various
molecular levels of activity.  In parts of South Asia, one effect of
the molecular activities associated with the implementation of the
"green  revolution" was to encourage the capitalization of well-to-do

farmers and various  entrepreneurs, while the poor peasants found  them-

selves  even worse off then before.  Thus, the previous interactions of
 *George A. Miller, Eugene Galanter, and Karl H. Pribram, Plans and  the
  Structure of  Behavior  (New York:  Henry Holt and Co.,  Inc., 1960), p. 13.
 tlsidor Chien,  "The  Image of Man," The Journal of Social Issues, Vol.
  XVIII  (1962),  p.  11.
 tlbid.
                                   134

-------
an individual, community, firm or nation state with the natural or social

environment may have a powerful effect on subsequent interactions.  This

is an important reason why changes in environmental policies are often

extremely difficult to implement.*

     Because of the hierarchical arrangement of many actions,  it also

happens that a molar activity becomes a motive for the molecular activi-

ties it includes.  Flood control—an undeniably worthy enterprise—may

provide the motive for lining natural streams with concrete; the mining

of much-needed coal motivates the stripping away of forests,and topsoil;

and so forth.  In some situations, a behavior may even "become a motive

of the behavior that initially motivated it.""  Thus,  since economic

growth may contribute to a country's power and because a powerful coun-

try may find new opportunities for growth,.growth and  power-seeking may

become reciprocally motivating—perhaps at the expense of other societal

values.

     Perceptual problems complicate growth-competition situations within

and between societies and contribute to another subtle, but very power-

ful type of problem.  No human being, including a head of state, can

even know for certain how his own actions will be responded to or inter-

preted by another human being.  And, in turn, he has no way of ascertain-

ing beyond any doubt what the other intends by his actions.  He can only

infer such predispositions and intentions by what the  other does (or has

characteristically done in the past).  Obviously, there is no  single,

best way of getting at such problems or of understanding better some of

the counter-intuitive aspects of nation-states and other large and com-

plex social systems.  But to some extent, they can be  attacked through
*_Ibid. ,  p.  10.
tlbid.,  p.  17.
                                  135

-------
computer modeling,  simulation and forecasting.   Several such techniques



have been put forward in the last few years as  tools for achieving a



better understanding of how social,  political and economic systems work.





     The objection can be raised that ultimately the critical problems



of resource usage are issues of human value that statistical techniques



tend to by-pass.   There is some truth in this allegation,  but there are



ways in which linear programming, modeling, simulation, and forecasting



can be used to identify and illuminate values rather than  obscure them.



Linear programming,  for example, has been used  in the past to optimize



war-time logistics,  and to maximize  commercial  profit.   It has been used



less often to optimize broader environmental or social  outcomes.





     Values are implicit,  if not explicit,  in all human decisions;  the



problem is, how to identify them and link them  with particular decisions,



actions and outcomes.  A crucial step in this direction involves  the



distinction between  professed values and what may be referred to  as



operational values.   In the analysis and operation of social systems



there has often been a great deal of confusion  about professed as op-



posed to operational values.  Speeches,  interviews,  public relations



handouts, memoires,  the preambles of treaties and other state documents



yield professed values in great abundance,  and  all too  frequently they



are accepted as true values.  Frequently,  such  data indicate much about



what a head of state, legislator or  other national leader  likes to  think



he subscribes to  or  what he wants the public or the leaders of another



country to think  he  stands for,,  but  very little about what he actually



does.  In general,  the record of the decisions  he has made in the past



(and the values thus operationalized)  will  be more accurate predictors



of what he does in the future.





     Any increase in a country's population is  the outcome of a conscious



or unconscious "decision"  on the part of at least two people to have a
                                  136

-------
baby.  Each invention and each technological refinement is also the



result of human decision, as is each movement of goods, each budgetary



allocation, each investment, and so forth.  And to the extent that each



datum represents the outcome or trace of a decision,  some value or set



of values is also implicit.





     A country's annual budgetary allocations are a useful and accurate



measure of the society's operational as distinguished from its professed



values.  Of course, one cannot conclude that all the citizens of a coun-



try necessarily approved the allocations that were made or shared in the



values that were invoked.  But the statistical data do tell us, beyond



any doubt, what values were in fact acted upon by whatever individuals



or groups were responsible for that country's investments and other



.expenditures.





     Through causal modeling, simulation and retrospective forecasting



the analyst or policy-maker can infer with a high degree of confidence



what values a given society has acted upon with some consistency over a



period of forty or fifty years in the past.  A projection can then be



made on the assumptions that past trends, and the values invoked to



produce them, will be continued for thirty, forty,  or fifty years into



the real future.  Having achieved this base-line forecast, or projection,



on the basis of very explicit—though perhaps unrealistic—assumptions



about the future, we can use sensitivity analysis or linear programming



to introduce alternate values—and observe the probable outcomes.  Mod-



erate or massive changes in energy and other resource usage can be intro-



duced and the probable consequences observed—with the rates of change



of other critical variables altered or held constant.  Theoretically;




all possible combinations can be tried out.





     For each alternative,  the effort should be made to ascertain not



only what social benefits and costs are likely to be, but also how these
                                  137

-------
benefits and costs are likely to be distributed within the society or

between societies.  In this way, not one or a few, but literally thou-

sands of alternative futures can be generated with all assumptions and

each introduction of a new value recorded and made explicit.  It will be

possible to introduce a new value in country A's decision-making and

watch the outcome not only for A, but also for countries B, C, D, et al.


Research Needs for Anticipating the Impact of Changing Resource Usage

     To understand the environmental impacts of changing resource usage,

it is necessary to examine the ways in which such changes are linked with

the levels and rates of change of population and technology—as well with

various social and political variables.  In these terms,  politics not

only bears on ecology but will increasingly involve the regulation and

management of population growth and distribution, of resource usages and

allocations and of technological advancement and applications,* including

the control of pollution.  The modes and characteristics  of prevailing

resource usages may be expected to influence—and be influenced by—

levels and rates of change of population,  the technological advances,

and social, economic and political mechanisms.t  The modes and charac-

teristics of resource usage during an earlier period may  also be expected

to influence resource usages in subsequent periods.

     Fortunately,  we need not wait for challenging events to take place

before addressing ourselves to them in systematic ways.   Tools are now

at hand to identify various important linkages,  to simulate historical
*Harold Lasswell,  Politics:   Who  Gets What,  When,  How (New York:  Meri-
 dian Books,  1958).
•(•Walt Anderson,  ed.  Politics and  Environment:   A Reader in the Ecological
 Crlsis (Pacific Palisades,  California:   Goodyear  Publishing Co., 1970).
                                  138

-------
process, and to generate future alternatives.  Appropriate data are



generally available, although much is of uneven quality, and great im-



provements need to be made in social and political indicators.  The ap-



plication of econometric, system analysis and operations techniques to



social and political as well as technical and economic problems may help



us expand our thinking and thus facilitate "social learning."





     Previously, unlimited growth and expansion have provided solutions



to certain human problems.  Today, however, many people see growth and



expansion as "part of the problem"—although others are equally disturbed



by the prospect of a low-growth economy.  Is there an unambiguous answer?



It is entirely possible that whatever we do in trying to anticipate



tomorrow's problems, we may once again set the stage for future diffi-



culties.  The equifinal nature of human affairs rules out certainties.





     Ultimately, the course of events will depend heavily upon the as-



sumptions that are accepted.  It is therefore of utmost importance in



both research and policy making to make operational assumptions as ex-



plicit as possible.  To a large extent such assumptions depend upon past



experience which can be elucidated through the application of appropriate



research strategies.  Alternative theories and models can be tried out—



with the result that the implications of different sets of assumptions



can be made somewhat more explicit and their implications systematically




explored.





     The course of events will depend also upon the values that are



evoked and acted upon.   Who is to decide upon the alternatives that are



to be considered preferable—and why and how?  Should "multiple advocacy"



be combined with "multiple theories," "multiple models" and "multiple



methodologies"?  Is "multiple advocacy" desirable, and if so, how can



it be institutionalized?  And if a strategy of "multiple advocacy" is




followed, how is it decided how the ultimate choice will be made?
                                  139

-------
     With an appropriate conceptual framework, new tools, and access to




data it should be possible to provide a favorable context for answer-




ing". . . if this then probably that. . ." types of questions.  What are




likely to be the broad social, economic and political (as well as tech-




nological) outcomes,  for example,  if current (baseline)  trends are pro-




jected to the turn of the century  or beyond?





     If current trends of variables other than resource usage (popula-




tion, and so forth) are held constant,  what are likely to be the direct



and derivative impacts (social, economic and political)  of various pos-



sible petroleum, natural gas, coal, geothermal, nuclear and other



programs?  What could be the social, political, economic and environmen-




tal complications of a major breakthrough in solar energy or fusion?  To



what extent will the further development of each of these programs in-



crease or reduce demands for scarce minerals and other hard-to-get re-



sources.  What are the implications for food production, quality of air,



availability of fresh water and so forth?  Can some of the "unanticipated




consequences" of each of these resource strategies be identified in ad-




vance?  What are the implications  of relatively equal as opposed to



grossly unequal access to critical resources within given countries and



among countries throughout the world?





     Since most of these questions have worldwide, as well as domestic



implications, what are likely to be the effects upon international trade?




The international monetary system?  International relations, including




international conflict and warfare?  What are the implications for re-




source usage (and its consequences) of  continuing competitions in nuclear




weaponry?  What are the domestic and international implications of the




exploitation of the continental shelf and the deep sea beds?  What are




the possible tradeoffs in terms of various international divisions of



labor relating to resource usage?
                                  140

-------
     To what extent can "steady-state" economies be developed—and would

they be desirable?  Can industrialized countries learn anything from the

"Buddhist economies" put forward by E. F. Schumaker and others?*  In

what new ways can the principles of inverse feedback be used to combine

regulated growth with stability and environmental protection?^

     To the extent that alternative responses are obtained to basic

". ...if this then probably that" kinds of questions, a foundation and

context will exist for the discussion of values, options,  compromises,

optimizations and tradeoffs and the solution of more specific or narrower,
perhaps more technical problems of concern.  But if we want even reason-

ably adequate answers, most fundamental issues of the future need to be

raised and examined within a context which brings biology, engineering,
economics, politics, ethics and other disciplines into systematic rela-

tionships with each other.

     More often than not, major redistributions of benefits and costs

have been an outcome of major disruption and violence.  Is it possible
to design and subject to controlled testing various new institutions and

other mechanisms for achieving—peacefully and with less disruption—some

more stable and equitable distributions of benefits and costs?

     Modern economies illustrate some of the problems that we face.  In
many respects economies today are the most developed and rigorous of the

social science disciplines.  But rigor has not been achieved without

cost.  To a large extent, economists have achieved success by holding a

great many "soft" variables constant, or even assuming them away.  This

tendency has contributed to the strength of the discipline, but it can
*E. F. Schumaker, Small is Beautiful (New York:  Harper Torchbooks, 1973)
fJack C. Page,  "Engineering Social Systems," Technology Review, Vol. 74,
 No. 8,  p.  43 (July/August 1972).
                                  141

-------
be costly—perhaps even catastrophic—in terms of solving human problems.

Indeed these "soft" variables are precisely those which pertain to human

motivation, perception, cognition, feeling, value, preference, decision

and policy.  To a considerable extent it is these "soft" variables that

tend to guide and influence the outcome of economic and engineering

variables.  A major effort needs to be made in the direction of expand-

ing essentially economic models to include various "soft" and exceedingly

"messy" social and political variables.

     Since resource usage, technology and work methods are continually

changing as human capabilities and values change, the nature of any

given economy tends also to change and to generate new characteristics
and new requirements.*  However, in view of several basic assumptions

that underlie the discipline—contemporary economics tends to perpetuate

certain biases, not always made explicit, with respect to how societies

have been, are now, or might be organized and managed.  In this connec-

tion, some of the ideas put forward by Schumaker could well be consid-

ered and extended.'

     Within this broad conceptual and methodological framework a large

number of  specific issues can be examined.  The few that follow are only

illustrative:

     1.   In a recent article entitled  "Lifeboat Ethics:  The Case Against
Helping the Poor,"* Garret Hardin has argued that foreign aid to "improve-

ment" and  "ineffective" countries with large and growing populations

should be  ended, allowing such  societies,  in effect, to sink or adapt.
 *P. J. Bohannan, Social Anthropology, p. 321  (New York:  Holt,  Rinehart
  and Winston,  Inc., 1963).
 •fSchumaker  (1973) .
 ^Psychology Today  (September 1971).

                                   142

-------
What would be some of the highly probable economic and political effects



of a Life Boat policy on the United States, other countries and the world



at large?  What other "models" might be tested?





     2.  A great deal more work needs to be done on social indicators—



including the devising of new means for measuring social well-being and



the overall quality of life.  GNP, useful for many measurement problems,



can be misleading as an all-purpose indicator.  It would also be useful



to examine ways of distinguishing "needs" from demands.  How can the



problem of "need" be handled equitably across national and cultural



boundaries?  Is it fair to assert that the satisfaction of "needs" in



the United States places a much greater strain on the environment than



the satisfaction of "needs" as defined in Bangladesh or the Sahel?





     3.  If rising prices for foreign oil were combined with a series of



drought years in the Soviet Union or elsewhere, what would be the effect



in terms of marginal land use in the United States?  What would be the



domestic and foreign consequences of a competition for marginal land



between grain-growing interests in the United States and domestic energy



extraction interests?  How much arable land can we afford to mine or




urbanize?





     4.  The acquisition of foreign exchange surpluses by OPEC countries



has already effected a shift in world wealth.  What would be some of the



future implications—diplomatic, political, economic, and military—for



the United States if this trend were to continue at present rates?  At



an accelerated rate?  What are the potentials for an "economic war for



survival"?  Would the United States be prepared to protect Japan and the




NATO allies—as well as itself—from extortion?





     5.  Are there grounds for the assertion that an oil exporting coun-




try that is also a food exporter has the possibility of dominating the




world in many ways.   How?
                                  143

-------
     6.  At a time when various peoples of the world, including revolu-




tionary groups and dissident minorities, are becoming increasingly aware



of and vocal about unequal access to resources both within and between




countries, new types of weapons are becoming increasingly available which



are useful not only for guerrilla warfare but also for political assas-



sination, highjacking and political-military blackmail.  It would be




entirely possible for such a group to present a country like the United



States with the choice of sending food or losing Chicago.  These possi-




bilities suggest a range of psycho-political-military topics that need




investigation.





     7.  What are the correlations,  if any,  between world energy flows




(production, consumption, imports and exports)  and world arms flows



(production, consumption, imports and exports)?  What effect are rising



prices for energy likely to have upon the manufacture and distribution



of arms, arms expenditures, and efforts to control arms?





     8.  To what extent, historically, have  the defense of trade routes



and the securing of access to critical resources contributed to warfare



in major ways?  What are the possible implications of such dynamics in



a world where demands are skyrocketing and readily available supplies



becoming scarcer?





     9.  How can the social, economic, and political feedbacks of tech-



nology transfers — the exportation of the "green revolution" to Indian



providing an historical case—be monitored and  analyzed systematically




in terms of positive impacts and also unanticipated and possibly unwanted



side effects and other consequences?





    10.  China—which used to be considered  energy-poor and where only



twenty-five years ago millions of people starved annually—now seems



able to feed itself and export energy at the same time.  We need to
                                  144

-------
know more about Chinese methods and their domestic and foreign implica-



tions and impacts.





    11.   In case of a major breakthrough, what would be the implications



of massive supplies of solar or other energy, more or less equally avail-



able for all people, in terms of employment, traditional work and leisure



ethics;  competitive economic systems, and so forth?





    12.   By analyzing trends in various countries over the last thirty



years in terms of population, technology, resources and their charac-



teristic patterns of allocation and distributions, it should be possible



to ascertain more as compared with less desirable combinations or ratios



of the major variables in terms of quality of life.  For any particular



country: in view of its territorial size, geographical location and so



forth (1) what would be an optimal population for a given level of tech-



nology,  or (2) if population is accepted as a given, what would be an



optimal  level of technology and production, or (3) if access to resources



is constrained, how could technology, production and various other domes-



tic allocations be adjusted or modified in the shorter run and population



reduced  in the longer run to yield an optimal quality of social, politi-



cal, and economic life?





     These are only a few of the many problems that confront us, that



are important for the future and that are best investigated within a



broad interdisciplinary framework.
                                  145

-------
                  REVIEW OF THE PAPER BY R. C. NORTH

                             Earl 0. Heady
                         Iowa State University
     In the first half of his paper, Professor North has given an ex-
tremely interesting and useful explanation of the interrelationships
among population, resources, and technology; and the manner in which they
have feedbacks to social systems, politics, cultures, economic systems,
commodity and resource demands, and environmental quality.  He emphasizes
appropriately the greater complexities of these interrelationships and
interdependencies as societies become geographically bounded by space and
cannot move on to other locations or draw down from other countries as
their populations enlarge against given resources.  It is, of course,
this set of interrelated variables and conditions which give rise to our
crises of resource demands against supplies (e.g., energy) and to growing
problems of environmental quality.

     He is correct that these complex systems are difficult to analyze
and that policies frequently fail because they do not encompass a suffi-
cient number of variables or facets of these complex systems representing
interactions among population, technology, and resources.  However, I do
feel more optimistic about research possibilities and potentials than is
reflected in the last half of his paper.

     Professor North touches on an extremely broad range of problems and
variables.   Some of them are closely related to problems of environmental
impacts linked to changed patterns of resource usage, while some are only
remotely so.   He discusses,  in this single paper, the more conventional
environmental  set of variables but also devotes considerable time to
                                   147

-------
problems surrounding energy,  international exploitation of developing




countries by developed nations through shifting from colonies to markets,




the green revolution in India and others—without indicating clearly how




these are part of the core environmental problem set.  The paper does




not "focus down" very clearly or sharply on environmental problems or




issues, or on where and how interdisciplinary research can be organized




and directed to solving them (although this was a major element in the




title of his paper).   But perhaps there is some merit that he did not



do so since his range over a broad set of problems and variables, not



all closely linked into the core problems of the environment, indirectly




suggests how difficult it is to understand social systems—either in how



they react to new stimuli or how they can be controlled to attain vari-




ous goals or ends.





     He is indeed correct in emphasizing the complexity of these social




systems.  He appropriately outlines their hierarchial nature and the



conflicts of interest generated therein.  Further, he is certainly on



sound ground when he emphasizes the interdisciplinary (or multidiscipli-



nary) nature of environmental problems and their cause or solutions.




Unfortunately, however, he did not provide a systematic outline or model




of how and where interdisciplinary research can be organized to allow



either  (1) better predictions of environmental impacts in changed re-




source usage or (2) solutions of problems and impacts that are already




evident and are unwanted.  Is this void due to the complexity of social




systems, including our universities and research institutes, which pro-




vide ineffective means for integrating the research of different fields



of social science and of social science with physical, biological and



engineering sciences.





     He correctly indicates that the different sciences, and even fields




within given sciences, have increasingly insulated themselves from each



other.  The reasons for this are quite obvious and need not exist.  They





                                   148

-------
exist for a collection of reasons causing scientists in one discipline



or field to talk to each other through their own journals, rather than



in solving problems on a multi- or interdisciplinary basis.  Part of the



reason for this "tighter trend" stems from the administration, research,



and graduate deans or universities and research institutes who (1)  hold



back promotions and salary enhancements unless researchers publish in



their journals, (2) will not promote personnel to graduate colleges un-



less they publish single-authored articles in referred journals,  (3)  give



little or no weight to a mimeographed or multilithed paper by a team of



scientists rushing research findings out to solve the problem of a com-



munity or set of administrators, and (4) other actions and restraints.





     True, these complexities prevail and Professor North seems pessi-



mistic throughout his paper.  However,  I believe there are means for



organizing multi- or interdisciplinary research for better prediction of



environmental impacts from changed patterns or greater usage of resources,



or in solving negative impacts that now prevail.  I have long worked on



an interdisciplinary basis and do not find the insulation that disciplines



and fields have thrown up around themselves to be insurmountable.  In



fact, it seems easier to work on an interdisciplinary basis with person-



nel of physical, biological, and engineering sciences than with those of



other social sciences.  I am a bit puzzled as to why this is true.   Per-



haps, in my case,  the methods of research and models available and used



by economists more nearly parallel those of biological and physical sci-



entists than other social sciences.  But to be specific, I also believe



that other social  sciences can beneficially draw on those same methods



and models—and at a later time will do so much more than now.





     I now turn to means of overcoming the barriers and insulation that



scientists have thrown up around themselves that prevent them from a



direct and integrated attack on priority environmental and social prob-



lems.  One barrier is the organization of our universities and colleges






                                   149

-------
by disciplines and fields therein,  with budget power allocated accord-




ingly.  This problem can be solved, and has in some instances, through




an organizational matrix which has  disciplines as columns and problems




as rows.  The rows have as much control over budgets and personnel as




do the columns and they become integrated accordingly.   Interdiscipli-




nary research can be encouraged by  university administrators who insist




on the importance of the problem,  rather than discipline purity, and



organize teams accordingly.  Administrators can encourage it through the



reward system which amply favors a  person whose name appears with a



group of others on a publication appearing elsewhere than in a 'pure




discipline journal."  (Our current  reward system tends  to be the inverse




of this approach.)  The grantor of  research funds can both suggest and




insist on an interdisciplinary approach and require that it not be just



a "paper proposal" for the same but is,  in fact,  exercised as the proj-



ect is implemented.  When university administrators or  donors of research



funds become serious enough,  they have in their hands the means of gen-



erating and implementing the  interdisciplinary research almost always



involved in major environmental problems.





     The individual scientist also  can accomplish much  more than he be-



lieves, if he is willing to amble across the campus or  to the next floor




of the institute and try.  I  have done much interdisciplinary research



with physical, biological,  and engineering scientists over the last 20




years.  I have yet to register a failure when I decided I wanted to work




interdisciplinarily on a problem.   I have almost  always done it outside




of a formal project or contract.  I have accomplished it by explaining




in detail the importance of the problem and the methodology to be used.



Quite frequently the methodology has involved concepts  (e.g., a produc-



tion function), research designs, and models which are  rather foreign to




the biological, physical, or  engineering scientists and he has been



challenged to attempt it.
                                  150

-------
     Thus,  while the various scientific disciplines have increasingly



tried,  or have been successful in, isolating themselves from each other,



I am much more optimistic than Professor North in our potential  ability



to mount interdisciplinary teams to tackle problems of environmental  im-



pacts.   Some of our universities, particularly state or land grant uni-



versities such as the one in which I serve, were created to serve the



public and help it in decision-making processes and in solving its prob-



lems.  Generally, they have good records in doing so and in carrying  the



results of research to the public through the cooperative extension serv-



ice.  In my state, we have a long history and tradition in carrying



policy analyses to the public—to help aid in choice and decision,  not



by prescribing a one alternative solution but by explaining the  tradeoffs



among alternative policy attainments or different means to attain a given



policy end.  If the public finds that state or land grant universities



(the research and educational arms of the public) are void in organizing



interdisciplinary teams to better predict environmental impacts  or to



solve the problems they have generated, it has a means to right  the



situation through the funds it appropriates or through the program ad-



ministrators it employs.  While we have too little interdisciplinary



research, we certainly have some, and both the public and university



administrators have within their grasps means for attaining more.





     I again express my optimism for the future, at least between eco-



nomics and the biological, physical, and engineering sciences, since



increasing knowledge and application of the same or similar quantitative




models fall in the domain of these different sciences.





     One obstacle in organizing useful interdisciplinary research for




practical evaluation of environmental impacts is the extremely short-term



and hurried projects under which the EPA extends its contracts.   The  time



constraint on many of these is so great that at best a "slap dash" study



must be thrown together, drawing mostly on the basis of what is known or





                                  151

-------
can be systematically "drawn out of the air."  At best,  these "quickies"




must be done mostly with models and data that already exist.   They give



little time for specifying original interdisciplinary models  and in gen-



erating data for their application.  An interdisciplinary approach typi-




cally requires considerable pre-study and various seminars among groups




of persons.  This added time for seminars and knowledge  buildup steers




some people away from interdisciplinary approaches (they say  they can do




more quickly on a lonewolf basis)  and is a step which is nearly impos-




sible under the short timing of many EPA contracts.







Progress in Modeling





     I believe the progress and potentials in modeling to predict or



evaluate impacts of technology and changed mixes and  levels of resource



inputs on the environment have progressed further and are more readily



applicable than is suggested by Professor North.   Of  course,  his empha-



sis tends to be on overall social  systems where the  task is admittedly



difficult, but he overly discounts the extent to which various types of



models have been applied and the further potentials  for  applying them.



For example, he states "Linear programming,  for example,  has  been used



in the past in order to optimize wartime logistics or kill ratios,  or to



maximize commercial profit, or to  serve the special  interest.   It has




not been used as often as it might to optimize broader environmental or



social outcomes."





     Actually, linear programming  has been used broadly  over  the last



dozen years to evaluate alternative policies and social  and environmen-




tal outcomes.   My colleagues and I used the method broadly during the




1960s to evaluate alternative farm policies and generate the  tradeoffs



in food costs, treasury outlays, farm income, export  potentials, rural




employment, and other "outcome variables."  We have  evaluated nationally



and simultaneously by 150 regions  the impact of large and small farm
                                  152

-------
technology on farm numbers, total farm income, income per farm,  chemical



and other nonfarm input usage, farm prices, consumer food costs,  rural



community employment and income generation.  We have applied a national



water model which evaluates alternative techniques, the substitutability



of land and water and certain environmental restraints in determing the



availability of water for food production, export tradeoffs and  urban



and industrial uses in the future.  We also have a very large-scale



environmental model of the entire United States for the land and  water



resources of agriculture which extends up to 10,000 equations and over



100,000 variables relating to 1,891 land resource regions, 50 water sup-



ply regions, 35 consumers markets, all commodities produced and  all tech-



nologies used in agriculture.  These models allow simultaneous evaluations



at the national, regional, watershed, state and other levels of  technolo-



gies, and land and water use practices on the environment.  They  allow us



to examine pollution levels or potentials in the absence of restraints on



soil loss or sedimentation, chemical fertilizer and pesticide use,  or



animal waste controls.  Similarly, they allow, region-by-region  or na-



tionally, evaluation of outcomes when soil loss, nitrogen and phosphate



application, pesticide use, and animal wastes,are controlled at  various



levels.  They are capable of quantitatively measuring income redistribu-



tions among regions and producer groups as alternative environmental



restrictions might be applied.  All of them indicate tradeoffs in envi-



ronmental attainment, farm prices and incomes, food costs, commodity



exportability,  resource conservation, resource values, and related 'out-



put variables."  Finally,  linear programming models have been used for



evaluations in particular watersheds and many other problem areas which



impinge on society.  While Professor North may be correct in stating that



linear programming has not been used enough, I believe that he is either



unaware or discounts too greatly the extent to which it has been used to




generate information for public choice.
                                  153

-------
     In general,  I believe our ability to model large systems has pro-




gressed further than Professor North suggests—particularly in the physi-




cal, biological,  engineering,  economics,  and demography fields.  Less




progress has been made in other fields of social science but also I be-




lieve the attempts have been fewer and more scattered.   Hence, I am more




optimistic than Professor North that we can both (1)  model these systems,




and (2) use interdisciplinary  teams in doing so.





     I do not understand why he separates and distinguishes between




linear programming, modeling,  simulation, and forecasting; I find this



distinction unuseful.  Linear  programming,  simulation (either systems



simulation or econometric simulations)  and forecasting  all involve spe-



cifying a model then generating data to make quantitative application



of the methods.  Typically, forecasting involves modeling of a behavioral



system, and a great amount of  it has been accomplished  in econometrics.




In fact, we have modeled a recursive econometric simulation model for



the agricultural sector, which allows evaluation of  alternative futures



and indicates the tradeoffs of different  policies as  they impact on soil



loss,  chemical  and pesticide  use,  commodity prices,  consumer food costs,



export potentials, treasury costs,  and so forth.  A  model is not separate



and distinct from mathematical programming,  simulation,  or statistical



regression forecasting.  Also, whereas Professor North  correctly points




out lags in choice and decision, but seems pessimistic  in handling it,




lag in decision processes also can be modeled through different quanti-




tative approaches.  Use of distributed lag regression models to reflect




delays in decision have been rather widely used.  Similarly, recursive




mathematical programming models have been used to reflect restraints on




the rate of change in technologies, resource use and decisions as re-



flected by a milieu of conditions giving rise to uncertainty.





     In the realm of environmental regulations, perhaps there is great



need for developing and applying more distributed lag or recursive models





                                  154

-------
so that we can measure and express the tradeoffs or advantages and dis-



advantages in (1) moving to certain environmental restraints on a step-



by-step or slower basis, or (2) making them fully effective at one dis-



crete time.  I doubt that all segments of society are able to adjust to



change as suddenly and discretely as EPA regulations sometimes suppose.



Hence, I suggest that research is needed which employs models with dis-



tributed lag and recursive characteristics to better outline the alter-



native rates or paths of adjustment and imposition of environmental



controls.  The distributed lag nature of adjustment, and the greater



long-run than short-run elasticity of response may have positive as well



as negative implication.





     Professor North mentions several times, seemingly with considerable



despair, that solution of one problem by one means typically causes one



or more other problems to appear elsewhere.  For example,  urban renewal



may create new ghettos, welfare programs may produce more crimes,  indus-



trial growth conflicts with environmental production, and so on.  Rather



than despair over these multiple outcomes stemming from a policy,  as I



believe is implied in his paper, I suggest that they present an immense



research challenge and an area that is insufficiently exploited in the



imposition of EPA regulations.  Rather than accept the notion that



"there's no reason to take action on a problem because its solution may



cause emergence of another problem," I recommend that more research ef-



fort be devoted to analysis of the joint-production multiple outcomes



that result from specific environmental policies, technologies, or mixes



and levels of resource inputs.  Models and means exist for doing so.





     However,  EPA is taking actions where these tradeoffs have neither



been inventoried or measured.   They need to be inventoried and measured



so that compensation can be paid sacrificing groups and individuals in



extreme cases.   We do try to measure these tradeoffs in our national and



interregional  environmental models.  Under circumstances of reducing






                                   155

-------
chemical fertilizer and pesticide inputs we find (1)  that total farm




income increases because supply is decreased and demand is inelastic,



(2) farm unit costs are raised to the individual farmer and his inde-




pendent profit maximizing alternatives are restrained,  (3) the environ-




ment is affected positively,  (4)  food costs increase  to consumers,




(5) the supply price of export commodities is increased and export quan-



tities are decreased, and (6)  farmers in areas of limited rainfall less




dependent on chemical fertilizers tend to gain relative to those in humid



areas.  In a similar vein,  multiple outcomes of a technology or policy




prevail for other resource uses affecting the environment.  I suggest



that this is a priority area  of research for EPA; that  we know too little




of these tradeoffs and more should be invested in research on them.  Eco-



nomizing in resource use where multiple products are  involved, as they



always are in the process of  allocating scarce resources, involves a



negative sloping (and even concave) production possibility curve; indi-



cating that as more of one goal and/or objective is attained another must



be sacrificed.  The rate of sacrifice (the marginal rate of substitution



or the first derivative of the production possibility curve)  itself may



increase as one goal or product is increasingly pursued.   Yet these are



rather standard concepts open to  model specification  and quantification.



I reemphasize that they are not reasons for despair,  but are entirely



researchable and represent realms of knowledge where  EPA is yet in ex-



treme poverty.





     I tend to view other problems and research areas in this more posi-




tive realm—in the sense that they are concepts that  can be modeled,




quantified,  and used to make  environmental controls more acceptable than




many now are.  Also, the ability  to conceptualize them  rather readily and




research them can provide information elsewhere where EPA and society are




in great poverty of knowledge and need the supply increased if environ-



mental programs are to be equitable in their distribution of costs and
                                  156

-------
benefits.  Professor North does mention systems that possess both micro



and macro components and relationships in a systems hierarchy,  and that



what is good for a subsystem (i.e., a micro component) does not always



result in a positive product for the macro or complete system.   This is



the crux of the environmental problem.  Elsewhere, it is given  the term



of externalities.  The large-scale feedlot can lower its costs  by letting



its livestock wastes be transported by air and water to other points



where other entities of society pay costs through a damaged environment.



These are costs which are external to the firm, or micro unit.   If forced



to pay them, its decisions and resource or product use and mix  would



often be different.  ly is the case of the industrial plant and fixed



point pollution or the city delivery truck and its use of fuel  and



throw-off of exhaust contaminants.  In some cases, the extent and nature



of these externalities are evident and simple steps to cause the produc-



ing entity to suffer their incidence and cost are available and evident.



In other cases, the situation is much more complex, the need for compen-



sation to prevent severe income and capital losses prevails and much



research is needed to identify and quantify the extent.





     I believe that existence of a hierarchy of systems does not preclude



progress in environmental improvement but poses great need for  research



where we now have too little knowledge.  I will cite some examples.



Numerous environmental restrictions now being posed or already  legis-



lated stand to reduce greatly the value of resources and income streams



for private property owners.  For example, Iowa has a soil conservancy



law which,  if fully and actually implemented, would restrict sedimenta-



tion and soil loss to five tons per acre per year.  But the outcome, as



reflected by an analysis we have made through our national models, would



cause the income of Iowa farmers to decline while returns to farmers



elsewhere in the nation would increase.  This outcome prevails  because



food demand is inelastic and a reduced supply enhances total income, but



distributes the increment to farmers in stares other than Iowa.




                                  157

-------
     A somewhat parallel case is that where a farmer has been using




pesticides and chemical fertilizer over a long period.  Society or con-




sumers at large have not previously placed a positive or negative weight



on improved environmental conditions relating to these inputs.  Accord-




ingly, he uses them and the return is capitalized into his land resources.




Now, suddenly society or EPA decides they are going to restrict or eli-




minate his use of chemicals and pesticides.  Since his income flow and




asset values will thus decline, it is possible that the sum outcome need



not be positive—unless we can prove that the gain in utility to the




rest of the community in society is greater than the loss in utility to




the farmer.  Interpersonal utility comparisons are generally impossible



and the only way we can guarantee a positive sum outcome is to compen-



sate him for his loss in income and asset values in refraining from use




of these particular resource inputs.





     The conflict between micro and macro or subsystem and total system




outcomes complicates the implementation of environmental restraints,  but



it does not complicate research in measuring these externalities and



redistributions and in devising means of compensation which will cause



them to be equitable and acceptable.  EPA is charged with action programs



to be implemented under a great void in knowledge of the distribution of




benefits and costs involved as these programs are discretely put into



effect.   This void in knowledge causes programs to be enacted on persons



and localities which impose no external costs or sacrifice on others but




must pay costs or restrain resource usage as if they did.  For example,




at a point of time in the future,  car and truck owners in the thinly




population areas of the Great Plains will suffer incidence of costs in




atmospheric pollution control as if they lived in New York, Washington,



D.C.,  or Los Angeles.





     Distinction needs to be better made between the location and time



of the resources and technologies  and their creation of externalities.





                                   158

-------
I mentioned the case of the farmer whose income and asset values are



reduced because he is siddenly restricted from using certain toxic in-



puts.  I proposed that compensation could readily be due him if we were



to be certain of a positive sum outcome in welfare.  However, if a new



technology which he has never used appears on the horizon and promises



similar toxic effects or externalities, it is a different case.  Pre-



venting him from using it does not depress his existing income and asset



values, and compensation hardly seems equitable only to cover this Oppor-



tunity cost foregone.





     EPA operates with a void of information about externalities,  cost,



and benefit distributions and compensation needs or justification.  En-



vironmental enhancement could be made much easier if this void were even



partially overcome through research which can be rather readily conceptu-



alized and implemented.  We are using our large-scale models to do so



for the agriculture sector, the major user of the nation's land and



water resources.  It is not an impossible complex task in which we must



throw up our hands in despair.  Frequently,  the distributions take inter-



esting twists.  We found, for example, that  if all farmers were required



to restrict soil loss per acre per year to 10 tons (since sedimentation



is the major pollutant of streams and also serves as the transportation



mode for nitrates and phosphates) farm and rural area income would be



greatly reduced in the Southeast because of  soil topography and more



abundant rainfall.  But at 10 tons soil loss,  farmers in the Great Plains



would have increased income because U.S. total food supplies are les-



sened,  demand is inelastic and this region has scant rainfall and  a



greater proportion of level land.  At a 5-ton loss limit, however, the



Great Plains also would have to change its technology rather drastically




and experience an income decline.





     Professor North discusses conflicts between short-run and long-run



interests.   The concept is a standard one in economic analysis:





                                 159

-------
discounting future income streams to arrive at present capital values of




different alternative future investments.  It is not a difficult problem



to conceptualize and model.   Discounting under alternative interest or




discount rates can even be incorporated into recursive mathematical pro-




gramming or other models to  evaluate different policies or subsidy and



compensation schemes to encourage conservation of resources for the



future.  In Scandinavian countries a complex of tax rebates, special low




interest rates tied to the purpose,  and even subsidies on plantings are




used to encourage tree farming—an activity which does not result in a



product until 30-50 years, as compared to an immediate income from annual




crops.





     Certainly means do exist which can cause conservation or protection




of resources to take on priority equal to or greater than current use.




It is a topic subject to research and should relate to the consumer as



well as the producer.  The consumer typically speaks to the producer in




one manner or signals one use of resources through the market mechanisms;




whereas he also may hold an  opposite set of preferences which cannot be



expressed through the market.  Policies expressed through subsidies or



monetary compensation may then be required to offset the consumer's sig-



nal through the market.   Soil usage is an example.  Consumers with higher



incomes place heavy emphasis on row crops and feed grain production to




produce fed beef.  The row crops encourage soil erosion, sedimentation



of streams, and proliferation of animal wastes.  These negative products




are produced because the consumer causes this mix to be the most prof-




itable use of resources.  The food producer does not exploit the resources



because "he is a bad man acting against society's long-run interests and




well-being."  However,  the consumer may simultaneously wish that the




streams be kept clear and that land productivity be preserved for future




generations.  He has no  way  to speak through the market for these out-




comes and offset his market  signal that the land should be devoted to
                                  160

-------
eroding row crops and fed beef.  However, he can vote appropriations



which allow the public to pay the farmer to cover the land with grass



and market grass-fat beef at lower suppy prices.





     Many problems of environment and use rates of stock resources fall



into this realm of discounting the future and speaking through the mar-



ket mechanism relative to preferences which the consumer cannot express.



It is an extremely important research area.  In contrast to ongoing EPA



policy, which in majority supposes that the producer or transformer of



resources into consumer products is a "bad guy" who should suddenly and



fully bear the costs of improved environmental conditions, it is one



which has been highly overlooked but should be researched much more in



the future.  Similarly, research or efficient policies to better reflect



and attain consumer and societal preferences, which cannot be reflected



through the market or are negated through heavy discounts of future



returns, should be undertaken on a rather broad scale.





     In summary,  I believe that EPA needs a much broader and longer run



research program covering the economic and social impacts of various



programs to alter and conserve resources and to protect the environment



from damaging technologies and resource use patterns.   EPA research con-



tracts almost seem based on the assumption that the organizations has



two years of existence—within which it must obtain all research answers



and impose all environmental restriction forever on producers and re-



source users.   The result is too many very short-term research projects



so strongly restrained by time that their products must be small and



incomplete.  Not  infrequently the research contract period is so short



and the problem is so complex that the time allowed is not long enough



to fully conceptualize the problem and specify the model—let alone quan-



tify it and come  up with systematic and well-based research results and




solutions.
                                  161

-------
     Similarly,  numerous environmental measures are enacted as discrete




acts and means,  without consideration of other alternatives and policies



relating to the distribution of costs and benefits.  As mentioned previ-




ously, environmental restraints are applied uniformly over the nation—




as if everyone lived in the nation's large polluted cities.  Also, it is




not necessarily true that societal welfare functions will be maximized



by absolute edicts requiring all persons to comply at their own cost to



an environmental restraint.  Often, the nature and pattern of the measure



can give inequitable distributions of the costs and benefits.





      In a preface paper to this conference, it was suggested that too



much EPA work has had two steps; namely, a physical or biological impact




study which found out that economic problems prevailed, followed by an




economic study which showed that other social problems also prevailed.



My recommendations to avoid these outcomes are for EPA to (1) drop the



"aura" that it has only a two-year existence to organize as many as pos-




sible short-run studies--and devote more resources to long-run analyses




which can better incorporate in single models the various physical, eco-




nomical, and social facets; (2)  devote more resources to policy studies




which evaluate all of the tradeoffs in changing patterns of technology




and resource use.  In the latter case, alternative policy means to reach




given environmental ends or objectives could be explored.  We could then



better indicate where and when subsidies and compensation should be used




to alter these patterns and who should receive them, as compared to




simple edicts or outright legislative prevention with which all must



uniformly comply even though some gain while others sacrifice in income,



resource values, and utility.





     Professor North has well pointed out the complex setting within




which fall actions to influence resource use and environmental impacts.




However, I am optimistic and believe, as I have emphasized, that if we



are serious, (1) we possess the means to organize the appropriate






                                  162

-------
Interdisciplinary teams; (2) the physical, biological, economical, and




social variables can be adequately modeled—especially in a large number



of cases if research projects and the view of EPA is turned more away



from "do tomorrow the research we wanted yesterday" to longer term analy-



ses; and (3)  alternative policy means can be used appropriately and ef-



fectively in overcoming the problems of externalities that characterize



environmental concerns.





     Finally, it is possible that EPA should greatly alter its approach



to research which has a focus on negative impacts and on restraining



technologies and resource uses which give rise to them.  The altered ap-



proach would be a more positive long-term one of catalyzing research to



obviate the need for technologies and resource uses that pollute the



environment.   EPA would become less a "hand slapper," through legislated



restraints of producer and resource owners, and more a leader to new



technologies that possess fewer negative externalities and environmental



impacts.





     An example policy could be directed to feed grain production.  Under



economic growth, declining real cost of capital and subsequently more



specialized farms have concentrated the production of food commodities



and increased both the use of industrial inputs and the emission of



products which are transported to streams (e.g., sediment, nitrate,



animal wastes) as pollutants.  Rather than purely a negative legislative



approach, EPA could catalyze identification and assessment of the 264 mil-



lion acres of Class I and II land (about 40 percent of land now cropped)



which is not currently cropped and if used, could lessen the concentration



of production.  It could catalyze research on the feeding of carbon diox-



ide to plants so that .greater yields per acre would allow more land to be



substituted for chemical and pesticide inputs.  It could catalyze re-



search on symbolic nitrogen fixation and pest resistance of the major



feed crops so that they could be grown over a wider area and be less





                                   163

-------
dependent on large doses of nitrogen and insecticides.   This more posi-




tive approach would require EPA to look upon itself less as a short-run




"watch dog" and more as a positive institution reacting in a long-run




cooperative manner with our well-established and  long-existing public




institutions, such as the land  grant universities and other federal




research organizations.
                                 164

-------
 RESEARCH NEEDS




THIRD VIEWPOINT

-------
             RESEARCH IN AN ACCELERATING HUMAN  ENVIRONMENT:
                          THE PROBLEM IN OUTLINE

                             Ralph C. d'Arge
           The hunter is camped on a great plain  with  a  small  fire
     providing a flickering light and intermittent  warmth.  Tiny
     wisps of smoke ascend into a vast,  clear night sky.  Tomorrow
     the hunter will move, leaving behind ashes,  food  scraps,  and
     his own excreta.  After ten steps these are  lost  from  sight
     and smell,  probably forever.  With  them he leaves too  his
     brief speculation about sky and earth,  brought on by the
     loneliness of night,  and he peers toward the horizon in
     search of prey.

          The Administrator of the World Environmental Control
     Authority sits at his desk.  Along  one wall  of the  huge room
     are real-time displays, processed by computer  from  satellite
     data, of developing atmospheric and ocean patterns, as well
     as flow and quality of the world's  great river systems....
     Observing a dangerous red glow in the eastern  Mediterranean,
     the Administrator dials sub-control station  Athens  and orders
     a step-up of removal  by the liquid  residuals handling  plants
     there.   Over northern Europe, the brown smudge of a projected
     air quality violation appears and sub-control  station  Essen
     is ordered to take the Ruhr area off sludge  incineration  for
     24 hours."
                                   Kneese,  Ayres, d'Arge1*
                                   (1970)


     To quote one's own coauthored writings as a  starting point for seri-

ous discussion is perhaps  highly presumptuous, but  may be an effective

device for summarizing quikcly a particular viewpoint  of the future.  I
*Footnotes  are  listed  at  the end of this paper.
                                  167

-------
obviously believe that environmental issues will become so overwhelming

as to ultimately require international control and problem solving.

     During the past few decades,  we have observed extremely rapid growth

in:  technology and technological  complexity, per capita income, energy

use, exotic chemicals, waste flows,  environmental disamenities, environ-

mentally related health problems,  and bureaucratic structures to "solve"

these problems.  And I suspect such  growth will continue unmitigated at

least to the start of the next century.   This suggests that certain types

of environmental problems may begin  to dominate our concerns.  To be sim-

plistic, let me taxonomically classify the types of environmental problems
by the following ground divisions:  (1)  extent of impacts, (2)  timing of

impacts.

     A quick glance at Figure 1 should indicate the direction toward

which I believe we are moving.  In terms of environmental problems, a

specific new class seems to be emerging.  This class can perhaps be typi-

fied as having the following characteristics:

          The problems are of long duration and may or may not be
          technically and/or economically irreversible.

     A current example of a problem  with the above characteristics is

the emission of fluorocarbons 11 and 12  into the atmosphere.   At current
(1972) emission rates it is estimated that the global decrease in 03 will

not reach 5 percent before 2064 and  the final effect on skin cancer inci-

dence more than a generation beyond  that.3  Consequently, economic-

environmental tradeoffs are over a span of at least 100 years.   Can con-

ventional benefit-cost analysis come to  grips with this highly uncertain

intergenerational choice?  I think not,  since a loss of our current GNP

($1 trillion plus) in 100 years at 6.125 percent3 would be currently

valued at less than $3 billion, less than the current gross product of

the Libyan Arab Republic.  Likewise, a loss of life at the fictional
"public" value of $250,000 would be  worth less than $600.

                                  168

-------
Extent
of
Impacts
Local
        Timing of Impacts
         Short Term
Regional
Global
     Irreversibility

Long Term   <
               | Smoke I I Lead Poisoning
                                                               T
            ]
                              [Thalidomide

                                    Asbestos Fibers
                                 Modern Insecticides
                        S!
                        D)

                        3
                        (t
                        01
         FIGURE  I.  EXTENT AND TIMING OF ENVIRONMENTAL IMPACTS
                                      169

-------
     A second striking example of the timing of impacts problem is the

storage of nuclear wastes,  thereby potentially endowing future genera-

tions with both the responsibility and risk.   Kneese has typified the

nuclear waste storage problem as a "Faustian Bargain."   To quote him at

length:

          "It is my belief  that benefit-cost analysis cannot answer
     the most important policy questions associated with the desira-
     bility of developing a large-scale, fission-based economy.   To
     expect it to do so is  to ask it to bear a burden, it cannot sus-
     tain.  This is so because these questions are of a deep ethical
     character.  Benefit-cost analyses certainly cannot solve such
     questions and may well obscure them.
          These questions have to do with whether society should
     strike the Faustian bargain with atomic scientists and engi-
     neers described by Alvin M. Weinberg in Science.  If so un-
     forgiving a technology as large-scale nuclear fission produc-
     tion is adopted, it will impose a burden of continuous
     monitoring and sophisticated management of a dangerous mate-
     rial, essentially forever.  The penalty of not bearing this
     burden may be unparalleled disaster.   This irreversible
     burden would be imposed even if nuclear fission were to be
     used only for a few decades, a mere instant in the pertinent
     time scales. .  . ."

     Other examples of intergenerational environmental tradeoffs are

plentiful.  What is important ethically on such "timing" problems is the
absolute inability of future generations to actively participate in

policy decisions.  While the environmental problems themselves may be

reversible in the future, the decision is not once made.  One special

case of the long-term timing of impacts is where, for the foreseeable

future, once an impact has  occurred it is forever irreversible.   That is

it will be impossible in the future to technically, economically, or

socially return to a previously attained or natural environmental state.

Irreversibility is defined  differently here than commonly used in the

physical sciences.  Irreversibility in economics is often defined as

being a new state where "there are no technical means of restoring the

                                  170

-------
original character" of the state.5  Draining of the Everglades,  construc-
tion of Glen Canyon Dam,  and the elimination of various natural  species
are often cited examples.  Economists have argued that the possibility
of time irreversibility of an environmental state requires the inclusion
of new nonmarket values for the extra loss inherent in making an irre-
versible decision.6  Whether such values can be measured for current
generations is now in the pretesting stage, but it should be obvious
that they cannot be measured for future generations.

     It is clear that environmental issues with irreversible aspects
have been growing rapidly in the recent past and there is no reason to
suspect an amelioration in growth in decades to come.7  What is  of  ex-
treme importance is a decision methodology capable of at least partially
accounting for actual or probable irreversible states.8  Conventional
decision analyses appear not to be sensitive to the unique attributes
of long-term and potentially irreversible outcomes.  We next turn to
another attribute of the new class of environmental problems cited
earlier.

          The environmental problems have suspected outcomes,  but
          these are only vaguely understood and may never be.

     Here perhaps is the heart of the difficulty in managing complex
ecosystems.  There may be a large number (at least as many as active
scientists or advocates)  of potential and feasible outcomes of a partcu-
lar environmental decision.  None are adequately quantifiable without
being substantially simplified and thereby reduced to a mechanistic and
sometimes arbitrary prediction(s).   This is, in my opinion, the  basic
problem of the "holistic" approach adopted by many environmental prac-

titioners.  To quote one obviously optimistic advocate:

          "The President  charged EPA to take a holistic approach
     to the environment,  to view it not as an isolated series of
     events or pollution  situations but rather, as an entity in
                                  171

-------
     which disciplines overlap and all segments are interrelated
     and interwoven.   This "systems approach" rejects as simplis-
     tic the notion that we can protect the environment or enhance
     the quality of life by stacking a series of separate airtight
                                                     119
     Washington-based programs on top of one another.

     Thus emerges a recognition that "everything depends on everything

else" and "complete modeling" will provide all of the useful answers.

What is not recognized is the basic uncertainty underlying most, if not

all, cause and effect relationships or,  more popularly, "transfer func-

tions."  Coupling basically unknown or only slightly tested relation-

ships compounds the likelihood of pronounced errors in establishing im-

pacts or the range of policy choices.

     As an example, if stratospheric flight through aerosol loadings

reduces global average temperatures by say 0.5°C,  policymakers would

like to know what impacts this will have on world wheat production by

region, prices, balance of trade and, most importantly, who will be hurt
and who will gain.  Given historical records (with few degrees of free-

dom) , researchers can model wheat yields by region as related to climate

and other factors (fertilizer use,  available equipment, farm knowledge,

frost-free days, soil type, terrain, elevation,  insect infestations)
and attempt to predict changes in yield by locale or region.

     Figure 2 shows a very revealing diagram of how winter wheat in all

regions of the USSR may vary with combinations of average temperature

and precipitation changes.10  Unfortunately, statistical data on yields

and all other variables are imprecise.  With given statistical and in-

formational error, predictions are made,  but the policymakers cannot

interpret an average 1/10 bushel decrease (or increase) in yield for

42 major global regions.  What they wish to know is at minimum dollars

lost and dollars gained by country.  In consequence, an econometric

model of world wheat trade needs to be developed,  again with historical

data.  The result is a set of statistical relationships based on $2.00

                                  172

-------
00
                                                                                                                      0.066
                                                                                                                      0.0
                                                                                                                     -0.143.,
                                                                                       0.0
                                           HINTER HHEHT
                                           RZIHUTH = 35
                                           HIDTH = 9.00
                                           HLTMIN= 0
RLTITJDE
HEIGHT  =
RLTHBX  =
                           'Views 3-D Plot developed by and courtesy of Environmental Systems Research Institute, Redlands, Californis

                            Special thanks are extended to Eric F. Harnden and Ronald Eid of the Department of Earth Sciences,

                            University of California, Riverside.
                        FIGURE  2-  PROFILE OF YIELD CHANGES (AY)  IN  WINTER WHEAT FOR CHANGES

                                    IN TEMPERATURE  (AT)  AND  PRECIPITATION (AP) U.S.S.R.

-------
per bushel wheat with no substantial climatic variations (1958-71).   Then
along comes a substantial climatic variation causing an extreme regional
shortage of wheat,  with the price almost doubling.   The models yield in-
accurate predictions on two counts at least:  yield is not calibrated
for extreme variations and neither is price, yet extremes in both will
occur almost simultaneously.   The net effect is to  almost nullify the
value of modeling for policymakers.   They do not want " surprise free"
estimates but the range of possibilities and likelihood of them.  But
such a range or "window" of possibilities is always bounded by the his-
torical past or the "reasoned" imagination.   As you are well aware,  the
"bite the bullet" philosophy of indiscriminate policy groping has per-
vaded in such situations.  Often there is an added  dimension, one which
Arrow identified as "learning by doing."11   Basically,  for environmental
problems this amounts to testing on a small  scale (small enough to avoid
thresholds) the impacts of economic activity,  be it introducing a new
cosmetic or limited multiple use of the stratosphere.   The question  is
how fast to allow emission or introduction without  surpassing irrever-
sible and/or costly thresholds.  And a decision methodology for such
questions is in need of development.

     My central point is that it may pay society to approach certain en-
vironmental problems in terms of a "guinea pig" approach,  where limited
testing is undertaken but not to the point of subjecting large groups to
substantial environmental risk.  By recognizing that at least a part of
man's technological future depends on taking some risk (and evaluating
it beforehand),  might we be able to have our cake and eat it too?  That
is, discovering new products that are both desirable and not very harm-
ful to either present or future generations.  The element of uncertainty
as to long-term future impacts will always be looming and depend crucially
on our understanding of both natural and perturbed  ecosystems.  But
"learning by doing" appears to be a dominant strain in human nature  and
beyond recall.
                                   174

-------
     A third characteristic of the emerging environmental problem is its

extent by population, by geographical domain, and perhaps by cultural

domain.  Let me generalize this characteristic as follows:

          The extent of environmental problems, in geographic domain,
          is growing rapidly; and in the future problems with the
          commons will be global or, at minimum, multinational in
          scope.

     About six years ago, rather facetiously, I suggested that if the

world were a flat plain, Los Angeles grew by a factor of seven,  and pre-

vailing winds continued, Cambridge (Massachusetts) would become  a recip-

ient of Los Angeles' smog.18  It received a long laugh but few serious

comments by the economists in attendance.  But perhaps Harvard is now

not so sure.

     With the advent of nuclear explosions and fallout, mercury;  oscil-

lation in fish species, continuous contrails, regionalized heat  islands,

multinational water pollution problems (i.e., Baltic, Mediterranean,

Great Lakes, North Sea, and Colorado River), the extent of multinational

environmental dependency has become apparent.  With oceanic oil  spills,

crowding of air waves, potential rabies transmission across Europe, the

recurrent flu epidemics constrained at Marseille and Genoa before spread-

ing to the European continent and the Americas, the "Cousteau" ocean

litter reports,  and worldwide fluorocarbon pollution of the stratosphere,

we have all become aware of potential "closeness."  What is obvious is

the degree of environmental dependence among nations even though tradi-
                                                                      1 *3
tional problems  of trade discrimination and power are still prevalent.

The "global commons" will be with us an an international issue with or

without the "oil Cartel."  In order to provide a bench mark for  studying

rational decisionmaking in a world characterized by the class of envi-

ronmental problems identified earlier, I should like to present  a short

parable.
                                  175

-------
     Let us assume that there is a world environmental agency with a




one-minded directorate that is suddenly confronted with the realization




that they will not be able to sustain life endlessly on earth.  They are




irretrievably confronted with finite and given resources.   Within their




"spaceship earth" are stored enough provisions to sustain life for a




period of time shorter than the communities'  "normal" evolutionary life-




span, even if they consume at minimal subsistence in terms of caloric



intake.  Clearly, if the communities' criterion of welfare is the singu-




lar objective of maximizing the length of existence,  they collectively



will not consume above the minimum subsistence level.  Alternatively,



they may be more or less myopic, depending on one's philosophy,  and de-



cide to consume at a faster rate,  particularly if they evaluate an addi-



tional year of existence at near starvation levels to be of less value



than an increment of present consumption.  The rational committee would



consume at a rate during each period of consumption such that they




equated the marginal utility of a  unit of consumption in that period



with the foregone opportunity, in  terms of utility, of consuming that



unit in any future consumption period including the period following the




one in which they run out of provisions.  The price of this foregone




opportunity will also include a positive shadow price for not being able




to consume below a minimal subsistence level  if such a level is constrain-



ing to their desired rate of consumption.





     From this extremely naive model, we are  able to make several infer-




erences.  First, if the committee  has a positive finite rate of time pref-



erence they will consider consuming at a higher rate than minimal sub-




sistence only if their evaluation  of an additional time interval of sur-




vival is not infinite.  Second, if their preferences and capacity are



such that they exhibit diminishing marginal utility of consumption indi-




vidually, they are likely to spread consumption over a longer time span




than if they achieved bliss through an immediate orgy of satiation.
                                  176

-------
     Next,  let us revise our assumptions and introduce the idea that



since the community resides in a sealed capsule, they must endure the



effects of their own waste generation.  The community is now confronted



with the problem that higher immediate rates of consumption will mean a



higher density of wastes to live with during future time intervals.   To



analyze the question of rational planning, let us stipulate the following



assumptions:   (1) the communities' preferences are such that they have



individually and collectively diminishing marginal utility of consumption



and increasing marginal disutility induced by expanding waste density;



(2) there is some waste density or concentration that is lethal to the



community and they are aware of this; (3) there is very little or no



assimilation of wastes or recycling within the "spaceship earth"; (4)  the



community has totally enough provisions to last all normal lifetimes and



this lifetime is a very large number such that their only binding con-



straint is their generation of wastes; (5) consumption and waste emis-



sions are joint products,  i.e., the principle of conservation of matter-



energy is operative; and (6)  the community is not decreasing in size and



does not discount future consumption at a negative or too high a positive



rate.14  These assumptions lead to at least two alternative rules of



rational decisionmaking, depending on what goal is to be achieved.



Rule 1:  If maximizing the length of existence is of primary concern,



the community will immediately reduce consumption to the minimal sub-



sistence level and remain there until decimation occurs.  Rule 2:  If



continued existence is not of overriding importance, the community will



immediately reduce consumption upon discovering the finite dimensions of



the planet  earth but increase it thereafter.




     The logic underlying this proposition can be seen by describing the



problem as  one of campers entering a campground and planning to stay for



some finite interval of time.   The campers are confronted with the prob-



lem that if they consume their provisions and discard waste at a high
                                  177

-------
rate initially they will have to suffer the "disutilities'  of this waste




during the remainder of their stay.   However,  if the campers consume at




a low rate initially and build up consumption over time,  they need not




suffer too much from waste generated in early intervals and yet increas-




ing consumption allows them to compensate for the increasing waste den-




sity.  At some point they will depart following an orgy of consumption.15



Whether this parable is plausible remains to be seen; but current "ra-




tional planning" is toward a "steady state" gradually in the long run,




the exact opposite of the optimal path identified here which is to move




to a "steady state" immediately, if  at all.





     Man is no longer a hunter within an infinite environment,  but he




may not have yet reached the pinnacle of despair where he must absolutely



plan for each year of future existence analogous to a virtually bounded



community.  He has reached, in my opinion,  a turning point—one that



could be irreversible; and one that  is dangerous for his future survival.




Let us turn to the question of what  he should  do now.  I would like to



set forth several assumptions on the milieu shrouding the interactions




between man and the natural environment as  I perceive them.





     First, and overwhelmingly, man  will not understand in detail the



interweaving patterns and forces within his own ecosystem.   (Me may be




able to discover parts and even at times the whole of a subsystem such



as how a particular wasp ovideposits eggs into the stomach of the larval




form of cotton leaf beetles.)  Why?   Because he can never observe all the




interdependencies that exist.  Laboratory experiments will never yield




empirical estimates of immediate and simultaneously long-term interactions




between thousands of species.  The ecological  system has been described




as a "Rube Goldberg" world with an almost infinite set of causes and ef-



fects. We can only perceive what our minds  (with the aid of digital com-




puters) will allow us to conceive.  And, being an economist, I would as-



sert that diminishing returns to individual inputs occur, not only for





                                  178

-------
men's minds, but also for digital computers.  Thus, we will continually



be faced with environmental uncertainties and substantive ones,  for which



little or no information exists.  This will induce, in my opinion,  the



continued appearance of the following type of problem—an uncertain world



with potential eco-catastrophies as a tradeoff with immediate but very



costly actions to reduce this probability.





     A fourth aspect involves man's conditioning to believe he resides



in a cowboy economy where by definition positive incentives yield posi-



tive actions.  But do they?  Restrictive effluent charges may include



firms to bribe administrators of control programs to look the other way



or design devices to electronically "jam" monitoring devices.





     The EPA's control strategy for vehicle emissions so far has empha-



sized new vehicle emissions standards but has left all technical deci-



sions to achieve these standards to the manufacturer.  The automobile



manufacturers have decided to utilize and develop catalytic exhaust



reactors with relatively low fixed costs but high operation costs rather



than other devices of a thermal type with potentially high fixed costs



but lower maintenance costs.  Whether catalytic reactors will be more



efficient is unclear now, but what is clear is that even if they were



not, allowing automobile manufacturers to make this decision would  lead



to their adoption.  The reason, of course, is that it is more costly for



manufacturers to charge a higher price for their product directly than



to pass on higher servicing charges to consumers.  This would not happen



in a purely competitive static market where all consumers had complete



information prior to purchase nor would it happen if less indirect  con-



trols were adopted.   Further, the decision to emphasize catalytic reac-




tors had induced expenditure on this particular type of technology.



Whether such expenditure is an efficient allocation of research funds



is at least debatable,  given current assessments of other possibilities



including the external  combustion engine.  Finally, the choice of





                                  179

-------
catalytic reactors requires the elimination of lead additives in gaso-
line with a higher "natural" octane rating will have to be produced.   It
has been hypothesized that such high octane gasolines without lead will
cause greater emissions of olefins and other complex reactive hydrocar-
bons.  Whether olefins or lead is the more harmful pollutant in urban
environments is not at this time known,  yet a decision for catalytic
reactors has already been adopted.   The indirect control strategy of
new automobile emission standards contains dynamic and uncertain ele-
ments which, if left to the choice of private and profit-seeking manu-
facturers, may lead to new externalities arising from the health effects
of olefins or unexpected vehicle operating costs.
     What this boils down to is the inability of society to adequately
predict and thereby regulate individual  behavior via the traditional
"tools" such as taxes, standards,  or subsidies,  since behavior is gen-
erally unpredictable and has not been adequately modeled.   Unimagined
responses may predominate unless intensive testing of behavioral "trans-
fer functions" is undertaken.
     A fifth major issue is the observed lack of ability of current en-
vironmental institutions to respond to the class of problems identified
earlier.  This is in part due to the internal-external incentive system
which aggressively supports short-term solutions of short-term issues
with little or no thought given to the long-term implications of either
the issue or solution.  Further, the incentive and administrative struc-
tures may not even permit active coordination and research on this class
of problems.  Research is needed on alternative environmental institu-
tional designs and internal incentive systems and on the optimal rela-
tionships among institutions at different levels of the administrative
or regulatory hierarchy.
                                  180

-------
     Can these five rather dominating aspects of the new class of envi-

ronmental problems be solved?   I believe so, but not by utilizing (ex-

cept in particular circumstances) either traditional tools of regulation
or traditional institutional structures for implementation.   The EPA

currently is operated as a reactive agency.  A particular problem emerges

and the EPA studies it and then institutes some form of regulatory action
But at least some damage has occurred before regulatory action is imple-

mented.  And in those cases where pervasive environmental consequences
emerge, such an agency is equivalent to a salesman inquiring whether  the
malaria patient would like to purchase a mosquito net.

     Let us briefly review the subset of environmental  problems taxonomi-

cally identified earlier:  they are long term in the sense that choices

now involve effects on multiple future generations;  they may involve

irreversible decisions now; they are vaguely understood as to all pos-

sible ramifications and may involve the possibility  that to  learn about

impacts, trials must be attempted, and finally; this environmental prob-

lem subset tends to be more than national in impact  and likely to be

amorphously global.  Can we design a decision methodology that is pub-

licly acceptable and yet socially productive?  Optimistically I believe

so but only with a well-conceived research design.  The following list

for EPA of general research needs may be useful as a preliminary design:

     •  EPA's research strategy in the past has been one of  spending
        dollars on every conceivable problem.  While perhaps such an
        approach assures "safety first" when all environmental prob-
        lems have an equal probability of being catastrophes, it is
        a bit naive today, even given current uncertainties.  The
        type of problems identified earlier seem overwhelmingly im-
        portant.   Let the lawyers and a few economists  haggle over
        the more mundane ones.
     •  Concentrate research funds on environmental  issues where
        "back of the envelope"  policy decisions are unlikely to be
        valid and where interdependencies and/or long range impacts
                                  181

-------
   are pervasive.   Enough has been spent on automotive emissions
   controls and mundane water quality models.

•  Develop approaches to weigh consistently intergenerational costs,
   benefits,  risks,  and uncertainties.
•  Initiate a research program on the problem  of environmental ir-
   reversibility,  including  irreversible losses  of flexibility,
   resiliency,  stability,  and resources.
•  Emphasize the development of simple,  straightforward,  general-
   izable policy models that are comprehensible  in structure and
   variables to policymakers,  and hopefully to the general  public.
•  Conduct research  in an experimental mode on new approaches to
   regulation and  human behavioral transfer functions.  That is,
   on a limited scale,  test  alternative  control  strategies  as to
   their behavioral  impact.
•  Develop an active research program on alternative  types  of
   instiutional structures for organizations involved  in  monitoring,
   regulation,  and policymaking for the  environment.
                             182

-------
                               Footnotes
1.  A.  V.  Kneese,  R.  U. Ayres, and R. C. d'Arge,  Economics and the  En-
    vironment:   A Materials Balance Approach (Johns Hopkins Press:
    Baltimore,  1970).

2.  Federal Council for Science and Technology,  CEQ, Fluorocarbons  and
    the Environment,  Report of Federal Task Force on Inadvertent Modifi-
    cation of the Stratosphere (IMOS), p. 28 (June 1975).

3.  Current rate of discount adopted by the U.S.  Water Resources Council
    for benefit-cost  evaluation of water-related projects.   The Nuclear
    Regulatory  Commission proposes the use of 10 percent for evaluation
    of  privately financed environmental projects.  A 10 percent rate of
    discount would reduce the present value of the $1 trillion in 100
    years  to less than $80 million and the "value of a human life"  to
    less than $20.00  currently.  See Environmental Report  to Accompany
    Application for Facility License Amendment for Extension of Operation
    with Once-Through Cooling for Indian Point Unit No.  2,  Consolidated
    Edison, for the U.S. NRC, Source 8.4, Appendix B (June 1975).

4.  A.  V.  Kneese,  "Benefit-Cost Analysis and Unscheduled Events in  the
    Nuclear Fuel Cycle," Resources No. 44, Resource for the Future, Inc.,
    (September  1973).

5.  Anthony C.  Fisher and John V.  Krutilla,  "Valuing Long-Run Ecological
    Consequences and  Irreversibilities," in H. M. Peskin and E. P.  Seskin,
    editors,  Cost  Benefit Analysis and Water Pollution Policy,  the  Urban
    Institute:   Washington,  D.C.  (1975).

6.  The various nonmarket values  have been called "option  value," "exist-
    ence value," etc.   For an exhaustive discussion of "option value" and
    preliminary empirical tests,  see J. V. Krutilla and A.  C.  Fisher,
    The Economics  of  Natural Environment:  Studies in the  Valuation of
    Commodity and  Amenity Resources (Johns Hopkins Press,  Baltimore,
    1975).

7.  In  recent years,  more than 5,000 new toxic substances  have been in-
    troduced  in the United States  per year with  little or  no understand-
    ing of  their long-term impacts on ecosystems.  The recent work  of
    Ames and  Commoner  in designing tests for probable carcinogenecity is
    a step  in the  right direction  but appears small compared to the on-
    going capacity for development of new, exotic chemicals.   The Toxic
    Substances  List,  1974 edition,  U.S. Department of Health,  Education
                                  183

-------
    and Welfare, Publication No. (NIOSH) 74-135, Rockville, Maryland
    (June 1974).  The proposed Toxic Substances Control Act, however,
    may through "regulatory lag" reduce the rate of growth in "potential"
    chemical irreversibilities.

 8.  Even if we abstract from the problem of future generations values
    and losses or now to weight them against the present, traditional
    decision approaches may be faulty.  Consider the following problem
    (abstracted and simplified from recent studies of pollution by
    stratospheric flight):
                          Temperature                       Cost
                            Change      Probability   (Billions U.S. $)

                             -lc°           .001             $400

      Unregulated  flight^—  0             .740                0

 Decision^               +.25c°           .259               -2
      Regulated  flight     <±.05c°         1.0               <.100
      Given  the  expected value criterion unregulated flight yields ex-
      pected costs of  .001  ($400) +  .740 (0) +  .259  (-$2.0) = $.118 bil-
      lion or a  net expected benefit!  But should society  take a 1/1000
      chance of  losing 1/2  the U.S. GNP?  I think not if the problem can
      be resolved for less  than 1/10,000 of GNP or less than a 20 percent
      increase in ticket prices.  For detailed  cost  and benefit estimates,
      see R.  d'Arge, et al, Economic and Social Measures of Biologic and
      Climatic Change, U.S. Department of Transportation,  GPO  (1975).
      For subjective probabilities of climatic  change, see Climatic Im-
      pacts  of Stratospheric Flight, National Academy of Sciences, Wash-
      ington, B.C.  (1975).

 9.    Gary H. Baise, "Regionalism in EPA:  From Programs to Policy" in
      L.  E.  Coate-P. A. Bonner, editors, Regional Environmental Management:
      Selected Proceedings  of the National Conference  (John Wiley and
      Sons,  New  York,  1975).

10.    The analyses were undertaken under my direction at the University
      of California, Riverside, by David Mayo and Jane McMillan.  For  a
      complete description, see D. Mayo and J.  McMillan, "An Empirical
      Analysis of the  Effects of Changes in Climate  on USSR Wheat Yields,"
      Draft  prepared for U.S. Department of Transportation, UCR  (June
      1975) .

                                   184

-------
11.   K.  J.  Arrow,  "Economic Implications of Learning by Doing,"  Review
     of  Economic Studies,  pages 155-173 (June 1962).

12.   R.  d'Arge,  "Economic Growth and the Natural Environment,"  in A. V.
     Kneese-B.  T.  Bower,  editors, Environmental Quality Analysis (Johns
     Hopkins Press,  Baltimore, 1971K

13.   While almost everyone would agree energy cost is now a dominant
     issue, it  depends fragilely on a "cartel,   and  as economists have
     recognized, cartels tend to be short-lived because it pays  for at
     least one  member to undercut the others provided the remainder
     remain as  a cartel.   The optimum is to be the noncooperative mem-
     ber of a cartel, realizing gains from the restricted price, yet
     selling slightly below in large quantities.  It is generally the
     economists assumption (unproved)  that such cartels are inherently
     unstable unless side-payments can be made among members.

14.   If  the community discounts the future, this implies it values con-
     sumption or death at less in future years than the present, which
     appears logical if the community has no future generations.  If it
     does,  then a case can be made for valuing future generations equal
     with the present, in terms of happiness, utility, or loss  due to
     premature  death.  If such a case can be made, then a zero  discount
     rate is implied, i.e., one that weights benefits and costs  equally
     for all generations.   For discussions of these and other  issues,
     see W. Schulze, "Social Welfare Functions for the Future,"  American
     Economist,  pages 70-81 (Spring 1974).

15.   Have you ever observed a group of campers having a big party on the
     first night of their visit to a beautiful alpine lake?
                                  185

-------
                  REVIEW OF THE PAPER BY R. C. D'ARGE



                              W. E. Cooper








     The paper focuses on one of the most important classes of environ-



mental problems concerning ecologists.  This involves the regulation of



residuals emitted into the biosphere from agricultural,  industrial,  and



domestic material cycles which are toxic, long lasting,  broad spectrum



in effect,  and mobile due to their solubility in water.   The author



correctly characterizes the future trends in resource utilization as one



of increasing intensity and distribution of emissions of toxic substances.



Toxic increases will occur particularly as synthetic compounds are devel-



oped and produced in a frantic effort to escape the ultimate constraints



of material limitations and the thermodynamic implications of dependence



on closed energetic systems.  He discusses the dominant systemic charac-



teristics in terms of future research, policy development, and manage-



ment strategies given technical uncertainties, time lags in the response



of the ecological systems, and irreversible damage functions resulting



from this class of ecological insults.





     My response will focus on the critical assumptions that must be



tested and  the new technologies that must be researched if d'Arges'  para-



digm is to  be operationalized in the real world.






Control versus Design





     The initial decision must involve the choice between basic strate-




gies of protecting the public from the results of residual emissions.



One alternative is to develop more and more sophisticated control devices



oriented towards regulating the flows of residuals at the points of  dis-



charge.   Such a system can be implemented through the market system




                                   187

-------
utilizing economic incentives and/or disincentives as presented in

d'Arges' paper or by constraints codified as performance criteria (emis-

sion standards)  or by liabilities associated with legal statutes prohib-
iting "unreasonable pollution."  Much literature and experience is avail-

able on all three strategies.  If one hopes to rely on the control ap-

proach given the cost of being wrong,  it must be designed to perform
flawlessly.  Given the specificity and dynamic nature of the ecological

system, the prices and standards must be regionally specific and equally

as dynamic as the object to be controlled.   There are a number of formal

characteristics of the control structure that must be researched and de-

veloped if this level of performance is to  be expected.  These include:

     •  Observability—It is critical that  sufficient parameters can
        be adequately monitored.  In a control system, what cannot be
        modeled must be monitored.   This monitoring must approximate
        on-line (continuous information flows).   Currently, many of
        the sensors and the information networks do not exist.
     •  Integration—The information must be integrated without sig-
        nificant distortion or deletion. The "biological" systems
        integrate with physiological weights (degree days) while the
        "human" system has a series of social weights.  Little is
        known about when and how to determine and then synthesize
        these functions.

     •  Time lags—All biological systems are characterized with time
        lags in responses to all kinds of stimuli.   Most human insti-
        tutions are similarly structured.  Because of this, one can
        foreget the myth of the "Balance of Nature."  These systems
        will not converge to equilibria.  The control problem is one
        of managing a continuously unstable system.  The instabili-
        ties are directly related to the nature and distribution of the
        time coefficients of the critical processes.  These involve the
        dynamics of energy, materials, and  information.  Not even the
        most simplistic analyses have been  completed in this area.  We
        are trying to design a control structure without even having
        the basic system characteristics as design constraints.  This
        is poor engineering.

     •  Energy Costs—One of the limitations to this approach will be
        the energy costs required to obtain adequate controls.  With
        high throughputs of materials (sewage disposal, agriculture,

                                  188

-------
        and the like)  and relatively homogeneous (simple)  systems,  the
        benefits will  probably justify the energy costs of construction
        and maintenance of the control system.   As the system is more
        highly dispersed and/or the ecological-industrial  couplings
        more heterogeneous,  the energy costs per unit control must  in-
        crease.   Little if any research has been directed  toward deter-
        mining when this control approach is energetically feasible.

     The alternative option is to assume that the control  structures will

not be adequately designed and maintained to prevent individual  or  insti-
tutional mistakes.   If the weakest link in the system is an individual,

then one must design the system to be "idiot proof."  We have just  buried

about 23,000 dairy cattle in Michigan because of PBB contamination  of  the
agricultural food chain as the result of a human error at  a routinized

but critical node in the system.  To design a system to be idiot proof,
one must utilize ecologically sound criteria so that the environment is
biologically tough and spatially buffered enough to assimilate the  re-

sults of a human error without experiencing irreversible effects.   These

criteria include:

     •  Spatial  Patchiness—Ecological systems  are exceedingly tough
        because they are composed of a redundant pattern of semiautono-
        mous biological units (communities).  In general,  human  activi-
        ties minimize  this critical design feature.  What  are the
        economic and energetic tradeoffs between maintaining environmen-
        tal heterogenity and increasing the costs of external control
        strategies associated with homogeneous biological  landscapes?
        Little research on this has been completed.
     •  Open Systems—Ecological systems are resilient predominately
        because they are open (at least to information).   Recolonization
        following local extermination is a major factor in maintaining
        bounded  instabilities.  Utilizing regional zoning  to maintain
        the integrity  of ecological enclaves is a critical design option
        to increasingly costly controls.  This is specifically true with
        lake,  stream,  and estuarine ecosystems.  Again, little has  been
        done to  determine required size, spacing, environment, and  so
        forth.   Ecological engineering is a future option  that must be
        researched.  The alternative is an electronic engineering ap-
        proach that is capital intensive and energetically costly.
                                  189

-------
     •  Regionally Specific—Local ecosystems have significantly dif-
        ferent properties and capabilities.  If the object of environ-
        mental programs is to protect the integrity of the "natural
        ecosystem," then the control criteria must be ecosystem spe-
        cific.  More intensive care must be taken with fragile systems
        than with resilient systems.  Exactly how one translates frag-
        ility into regional emission standards, land-use patterns, and
        capital investment strategies is only poorly understood.

Other Related Issues

     There are a number of other issues related to points presented in

Ralph d'Arges' paper.   I will discuss these briefly in a somewhat random
order.  The list is not inclusive, but will more than keep EPA busy if

they attempt to concentrate on all of them at once.

          Distributive Source—Considerable work has been completed by
economists and engineers on the control and design options of dealing

with point source emissions.   The problems of dealing with distributive
sources is far more ecologically important and technically difficult.
In Michigan, we have buried over 4 million salmon because of PCBs in the
fish.  No feasible substitutes are currently available for use in trans-
formers and capacitors, and no one is yet capable of preventing dispersed
and multiple inputs of PCB into the biosphere.   User charges and discharge
standards do not do a  bit of good to the fish in Lake Michigan.   Consid-

erable effort should be spent in identifying and solving problems associ-
ated with synthetic compounds with these generic characteristics.  With

the approximately 500,000 synthetic compounds currently produced and dis-

charged, I am sure that similar "horror stories" are carefully nested
within the pot of social ignorance.

          Management by Objectives—Ecologists have considerable flexi-
bility in the design of biological landscapes.   If you want Lake Erie to
produce animal protein, you could manage it concurrently as a. tertiary

treatment plant and as a carp farm and most probably maximize its
                                  190

-------
 "throughput"  of materials and energy.   If society wants a  "Walleye  Pike"



 lake  and  gets one,  there is  no problem.   If they want a "Carp  Pond" and



 get one,  again no problem.   But,  if they want Walleye Pike and get  Carp,



 society calls it a  polluted  lake.   As  far as I can tell, we have NO



 management objectives  towards which we can work with  both  control and



 design strategies.   Given this, we most  probably will have to  assume



 multivariate  objectives  and  attempt to minimize unhappiness.   Nobody



 will  really win.  How  can EPA policies suboptimize distributive systems



 that  are  nonlinear,  hierarchically organized,  with time lags when society



 has a large number  of  object functions?





          Perturbation Experiments—Considerable importance  is attributed



 to the concept of irreversibility.   At the population level of ecologi-



 cal organization, extinctions of species is an obvious  irreversibility.



 The majority  of social concern over "threat to the environment," however,



 involves  community  level  ecological responses.   At this  level, species



 populations are expendable.   Extinction  is one of  the more deterministic



 events in ecology,  given  a long enough time horizon.  What is uncertain



 is knowing the  limits  to  the community's ability to "adequately recover"



 from  external perturbations.   Community  ecology is only  in an embryonic



 stage of development.  Our ability  to  model  community dynamics and antic-



 ipate biological significance  is extremely limited.   Empirical experimen-



 tation must be  utilized to gain immediate  insight  into  the array of



 response behaviors for various types of  communities.  You systematically



 kick them and see which way  they jump.   Determinations of the frequency,



 intensity, and distribution of external  insults  that are critical at



 various  seasons in the year must be obtained.   Good, old field experi-



 mentation  is  probably the best way  to  start.





          Open Loop  versus Closed Loop Controls—A basic problem arises



when  one  considers  controls over a  system where public and private com-



ponents are coupled.  The environment  is generally considered public and





                                  191

-------
the major emphasis is given to the responsbilities of stewardship.  The




private sector deals with a subset of resources that enter the market




due to their societal utility.  This component emphasizes the rights of




ownership.  When coupled together, the private sector more often oper-




ates around the benefit/cost of being right, while the public sector



makes decisions around the risk/cost of being wrong.  There is no way




that the Michigan Allied Chemical Company or the Michigan Farm Bureau



can compensate the people of Michigan for the damages resulting from



their errors with PBBs .  Neither can Reserve Mining be held accountable,



if the asbestos from their taconite tailings entering Lake Superior is



causing intestinal cancer.  Control policies that internalize the lia-




bilities of being wrong in necessary and sufficient forms must be devel-



oped if the control approach is to function satisfactorily.





     The above are a subset of issues resulting from the paper presented



by Ralph d'Arge.   The selection reflects my personal priorities of needed



research that should be initiated soon.   Many of these are generic de-



faults in our current institutional approaches to research and manage-



ment and,  therefore, are common to constellations of perceived problems



such as energy, food production,  land use,  nuclear waste, and so forth.



If EPA is really a regulatory agency,  and if their goal  is to manage the




couplings between industrialized  societies  and their ecological environ-




ment,  then the research  priorities must  be  cast in a testable and useful



fashion compatible with  a general system paradigm of control  and design.
                                  192

-------
 RESEARCH NEEDS




FOURTH VIEWPOINT

-------
                        RESEARCH FOR REGULATORS

                          George M. Woodwell
                     Marine Biological Laboratory
                       Woods Hole, Massachusetts
     Georges Banks is a large shoal area off southern New England.   It
is one of the world's richest fishing grounds and an area of spawning
and nurture for the fisheries of the northwestern Atlantic.   Georges
Banks is also one of two or three of the most promising sites for oil
exploration on the eastern seaboard.  Almost no one believes that oil
wells in the area will enhance the fisheries; some believe the develop-
ment will be disastrous.

     The controversy surrounding the prospect of oil developments on fish-
ing grounds is a good example for us because of its contrasts.   The in-
dustrial machine, starving for oil, monstrous,  wealthy, politically power-
ful, is driven by soaring oil prices to compete on the fishing grounds
with a hunting-and-gathering culture that harvests poorly managed natural
ecocystems that are obviously being rapidly degraded by over-harvest and
other factors quite apart from oil.  When measured by our economic system,
the fisheries have at present small value compared to the value of the
oil.  The oil interests, if allowed, could buy the fishery or any part of

it they damaged.

     The situation seems anomalous:  with starvation endemic in larger
and larger areas  of the world,  how can the value of industrialization so
far exceed the value of food that the search for oil can displace fisher-
ies, a potentially renewable source of protein and virtually the only
method we have of harvesting food from two-thirds of the surface of the

earth.

                                  195

-------
     There are many reasons and one can pick and choose.  One reason is




simply that those who are hungry are hungry because they are poor.  They



are not participants in international commerce in food or almost any-




thing else.  Their needs are not a factor in the controversy except as



governments choose to make them so.  The rich, those who have energy,




are not yet short of food and the economic system has not swung to put



these values in balance.  It may never do so;  such is the complex of




forces in the economics of resources.





     If our perspective is of the world as a whole,  the world needs the




fishery more than it needs the oil.  If our perspective is limited to the



national level, the competition among industrial nations may demand the




oil now in support of our own position in politics and commerce.  Because




we have enough food at the moment, we can lose the fishery if need be.





     If we ignore one perfectly sound stance,  despair, there are two




polar schools among those who explore such issues.  Certain technologists,



politicians, economists, and others believe still in the salvation of a



technological growth that feeds economic growth indefinitely.  Energy is




the key; with cheap energy we can make whatever other resource we require,



potentially including food.   On this basis a no-holds-barred approach to



energy is justified.  The fishery is a trifling cost.  No research is



required and no regulation appropriate.





     Others argue with equal force that technology has made no new re-




source; it has simply allowed the transformation and transport of other



resources around the earth to forms and places convenient for man.  They




would not abandon technology; far from it, but they would assert that



the benefits of industrial growth, at least in the present form of indus-




try, are finite and are now outweighed by costs not yet properly tallied.



Industry will not follow this path, of course.  It falls to the regula-



tors—to government.
                                  196

-------
     The arithmetic of exponential growth, growth in population, growth



in demand for food and other resources; coupled with recognition of



finite oil reserves, limited agricultural production, the effects of the



accumulation of CO2 in the atmosphere, the effects of released of sulfate



and nitrates into air, the leveling of fisheries yields, the limitations



of debt in cities, the problems of sewage treatment, nuclear waste sto-



rage, limited fresh water supplies, the growth of welfare and many other



new constraints all assure not only the series of changes in our lives



that we see in motion now but soaring pressures on all resources.  Almost



no one will accept an unbridled reliance on growth and technology these



days.





     The confrontation between the industrial system with its emphasis



on short-term profits and those segments of human welfare that depend on



biotic resources, the competition we see between oil and fisheries in the



northwestern Atlantic, will become steadily more commom and more acute.



This does not address the competition within the fishery among those who



would harvest fish; that competition too, is soaring.  More than that,



the pressures cannot be isolated, geographically or politically.  Air



and oceans are international resources.  How must their use be regulated?



What is fair?  What research will best support that regulation?  How can



we best "restore and enhance the quality" of environment as the Water



Pollution Control Act Amendments of 1972 command?





     There seems to be very little choice.  The pattern we have at the



moment is largely based on the false assumption that resources are large



in proportion to the pressures we place on them and that this relation-



ship will hold indefinitely.  A corollary has been the concept of an



"assimilative capacity," presumably a finite capacity for absorbing a




waste,  a series of wastes,  or an effect.
                                  197

-------
     An assimilative capacity can presumably be divided among different




users, and redivided as potential users increase in numbers.   It is



elusive, however.   A stream may have the capacity for oxidizing organic



matter at a certain rate and be assigned an assimilative capacity.   But



the reality of such an assimilative capacity for organic matter does not




automatically extend to other substances introduced with the  organic



matter.  We believe that there is no assimilative capacity for DDT  and




other toxic chemicals.  The concept of assimilative capacity  is not




merely vague but illusory.   It encourages a pattern of use of water and



air that virtually assures  progressive degradation by encouraging the



assumption that pollution is acceptable.   The burden of regulation,




which is government's, becomes virtually impossible:   the criteria  are




necessarily vague, the sources of pollutants may be large and numerous,



the political and  economic  pressures to allow various pollutions, con-




tinuous.  Small wonder that the system fails;  it is designed  to fail.





     Added to this is the difficulty of regulating it.   There is a  per-



fectly reasonable  propensity for a species-by-species and toxin-by-toxin



approach using classical toxicological techniques.   The array of species,



the problems of culturing them, the array of toxins,  the possibility of



interactions, the  remoteness of laboratory from nature all make such



approaches virtually impossible when pressures to exploit are high.





     The alternative is clear.  In a world condemned to soaring popula-



tions and more rapidly soaring demands on resources,  the basic pattern



in use of environment must  be the closed system:  countries that do not



infringe on one another by  fouling air or water held in common; cities




that recirculate their water, nutrients,  metals, and certain  fibers; in-



dustries that accept responsibility for their wastes as they  do their




saleable products; agriculture that does not poison waterways with  pes-



ticides or fertilizers; and power plants that do not infringe on biotic




resources with extraordinary demands for cooling waters.  This pattern






                                  198

-------
of use of the surface of the earth is the cost of intensive use.   The



basic principle is no pollution; not pollution within limits.





     You will immediately think of exceptions:  How can we burn fossil



fuels without releasing COa?  The answer of course is that we  cannot,



but it is conceivable that the amount of C02 emitted in total  should be



a matter of public interest and, possibly, controlled.   Certainly the



amount in the atmosphere, its patterns of circulation,  its fate,  and its



effects through the next years should be known.  We can make clear deci-



sions to allow normal geochemical fluxes to be modified within certain



limits, if we choose.  But the central principle remains the preserva-



tion of the earth's basic chemical and biotic patterns.





     All of this is set forth to establish the background for  discussing



the research that is appropriate for the EPA in support of its regulatory



activities.  The early steps in the transition toward closed systems have



been written into the law.  The policy statement of the Water  Pollution



Control Act Amendments of 1972 set that forth boldly and the law  itself,



complex as it is, provides details of the transition.  No one  expects  a



transition to closed systems to occur immediately.  Indeed,  the transi-



tion will probably not occur until its feasibility has been demonstrated.



It is a challenge for the EPA to provide the background necessary in re-




search.





     The research program in support of this transition is obviously



going to be complex, developed over a period of years,  and include much



of the work already under way in support of current patterns of regula-



tion.  I shall mention three segments that should be added now as a part



of the program that must emerge:  first, a continuing analysis of the



world carbon budget; second, a new program designed to discover the de-



tails of biotic impoverishment and how to recognize the earliest stages



of it;  and third, new ventures in the recirculation of water and nu-




trients in sewage.   I have chosen these not only because they  are




                                  199

-------
important topics,  but because they are examples of types of research in




which the EPA must now become expert.   I can do no more than outline




these topics superficially.





     The basic resource in support of  human activities is carbon fixed




in photosynthesis  and made available in various forms to man.   There is



abundant evidence  that the world carbon budget is being affected grossly



by human activities.   The major evidence is through the accumulation of




carbon dioxide in  air.  The concentration is now increasing at the rate



of about 1.5 parts per million per year and the rate seems to  be increas-



ing.  The cause of the increase is generally believed to be the combus-




tion of fossil fuels  but the destruction of forests and the oxidation of



humus are probably also contributory causes.  Despite the fact that two-



thirds of the surface of the earth is  water, two-thirds of the total



photosynthesis on  earth occurs on land and most of that is attributable




to forests.   There is good reason to believe that the total amount of




photosynthesis on  earth is diminishing,  although there is at present no




detailed analysis  of  this problem.





     To the extent that photosynthesis is a measure of the functioning




of the biosphere,  a decline in worldwide photosynthesis would  be a seri-



ous matter.   There is moreover the possibility that increasing amounts




of C02 in the atmosphere will lead to  temperature and climatic changes



that can occur suddenly and change agricultural productivity over large




areas.  The topic  is  of obvious importance to governments and  it would



seem that the EPA  would do well to develop primary competence  in it,



either through research in its own laboratories or through research under



contract in other  places.





     The second topic emerges from a detailed consideration of the first.




If we accept the principle of ecology  that the qualities of the biosphere




essential for support of man are maintained by the matrix of late suc-



cessional ecosystems  that have dominated the earth throughout  all of




                                  200

-------
human history, then we recognize that the preservation of this matrix is



a major challenge in the regulation of human activities.  Chronic or



long-lasting changes in the physical or chemical environment bring changes



in the biotic structure of this matrix of natural systems.  The changes



themselves are an index of the effects of man.  Just as changes in bird



populations gave us clues that persistent pesticides were accumulating



in places they should not be, so changes in the incidence of disease in



forests, changes in the composition of phytoplankton communities,  changes



in the spectrum of zooplankton and fish in bays give us an indication



that the physics or chemistry of environment has been modified.





     With experience we learn that the patterns of change are consistent



among many types of disturbance in any community.  The patterns of change



in terrestrial systems extend not only from shifts in populations  of



plants and animals but to reductions in net primary production and to



increased fluxes of nutrients into waterways.  Thus we can predict with



broad accuracy the effects of long-term exposure of forests to acid



rains.  We will be able to predict in detail the amount of acidity re-



quired to cause varying degrees of damage.   We require now,  first,  rec-



ognition of the patterns of change associated with chronic disturbance;



second, the establishment of quantitative relationships between disturb-



ance and the degree of change produced.   The work must be both terres-



trial and marine.   It spans the full gamut of studies of natural eco-



systems.   The knowledge gained from it,  however,  will be the basic



knowledge required for management of the earth's surface.





     The third topic is somewhat less ephemeral and one in which I have



acquired considerable recent experience:   the treatment of sewage.   The



review that I have offered here makes it abundantly clear that the pat-



tern of sewage disposal we have developed over the past century or so is



totally inconsistent with continuously expanding and ever more intensive



use of environmental resources.   Even the most modern and bold steps in
                                  201

-------
the current pattern will not stand scrutiny under this test.   The devel-




opment of large collecting systems for urban areas with the objective of




releasing treated sewage into the coastal  oceans makes no sense whatso-




ever if one recognizes a shortage of fresh water,  a shortage of ferti-



lizer elements, the problems of pollution  of coastal oceans,  and an



increasing shortage of energy.   One of the costs of having cities is the




recovery of sewage, the release of usable  fresh water into places where



it will be available again,  and the recovery of nutrients.





     The possibilities for making changes  in the patterns of treating




sewage are bein.g explored in various places around the world.   They in-



clude especially the use of  man-made or natural ecosystems for filtering



particulate matter, absorbing nutrients, and releasing fresh water either



into surface water courses or into ground  water channels.   Experience at



Brookhaven over the past several years has led me to be convinced that




both of these are practical  approaches.   It is possible to devise agri-




cultural and natural terrestrial communities,  used in sequence,  to treat



sewage over the long term.  The treated water is released into the ground




water for reuse as drinking  water.   It is  also possible to treat sewage



on the surface by a combination of marshes and ponds and to release the



treated water into a variety of uses including the irrigation of agri-



culture or the recharge of streams.   These studies obviously have a much




longer term to run but their potential cannot be dismissed.





     Some such plan for management of liquid wastes is clearly essential.




When coupled with the requirement that industrial wastes not be intro-



duced into municipal collection systems but be treated at the site of




the industry, the development of biotic communities for the management




of both water and nutrients  in domestic sewage becomes very attractive



indeed.  It offers the possibility of larger numbers of smaller treat-




ment facilities located in various places  rather than simply on the mar-




gins of rivers or bays in places where disposal of water in large






                                  202

-------
quantities is convenient.  It is my belief that the EPA must pursue



these techniques with all vigor immediately and that the proceeds of



this research will be extraordinarily rewarding.





     The issues of management of environment seem excessively complicated,



coupled as they are to economic interests, to historical views of rights



in resources, to traditional views of politics, and to what every man



thinks of as his own personal freedom.  They are complicated only if we



wish them to be so.  The central principles of the science of environ-



ment are no more complicated than the central principles of thermody-



namics or literacy or arithmetic.  Their essentials help us see with some



clarity and simplicity what is happening and how to solve the problem.





     The problems can be solved but only by rearranging our approaches



into a pattern that can lead to a solution.  To the extent that we devote



ourselves to accentuating the trends of the past decades that tend to



cause the further diffusion of human influences around the globe, we



become causes rather than cures.  There is a powerful argument at pres-



ent that much of the scientific effort of the country including that of



some of its major national laboratories is more detrimental than con-



structive.  It is long past time that we changed this situation.
                                   203

-------
                 REVIEW OF THE PAPER BY G.  M. WOODWELL
                           Sidney R. Galler
                      U.S. Department of Commerce
     Dr. George Woodwell is a distinguished ecologist whose contributions
to our understanding of natural ecosystems have deservedly received high
praise and international recognition.  It is not surprising,  therefore,
that the high point of Woodwell's presentation is his eloquently articu-
lated ecological perceptions which, appropriately enough, come into
sharp focus midway in his paper:   "in a world condemned to soaring popu-
lations and more rapidly soaring demands on resources, not to speak of
demands on the regulators, the basic pattern in use of the environment
must be the closed system:  countries that do not infringe on one another
by fouling air or water held in common; .... The basic principle is
no pollution; not pollution within limits."

     However, the intellectual climb up to this sunny promontory is both
steep and labored for this reader.  The descent is even more  precipitous
with the high point of the discussion quickly lost in a mist  of pessi-
mistic observation on the state of mankind's environmental affairs,  sim-
plistic diagnosis of the environmental maladies,  and an ingenuous pre-
scription for solutions.

     I find no fault with Woodwell's basic proposition even though I am
not prepared to rule out the potential for developing a technology that
could yield enough energy to meet human demands without degrading the
environment.   However,  I do take exception to his opening Georges Bank
illustration and I disagree vigorously with his proposed designation of
a Federal regulatory agency to be responsible for the support of the
                                  205

-------
requisite research programs that will  have to provide the knowledge for




meeting the needs of both man and his  natural environment.





     First, let us examine the validity of Woodwell's selection of the




proposed outer continental shelf oil development in the Georges Banks




area as the opening scene in his scenario  for justifying his concept of



the closed system.  The Georges Bank controversy,  while genuine,  derives



from the spurious notion that offshore oil development and  a healthy com-



mercial fishery must always remain mutually exclusive.  It  has yet to be



established that outer continental shelf-oil exploration and extraction



are intrinsically harmful to marine fisheries,  notwithstanding vocifer-



ously voiced allegations.  The facts are that the  great bulk of oil pol-




lution of the oceans stems from a combination of tanker deballasting



operations and runoff from shoreside point sources .  Oil pollution re-



sulting from accidental oil spillage,  e.g.,  tanker collisions, pipeline



ruptures, etc., runs a distant second,  while oil pollution  from station-



ary platforms, including the Santa Barbara channel episode,  has been



negligible by comparison.





     Undoubtedly, sloppy practices and inadequate  quality control meas-




ures have caused oil pollution and damage  to marine ecosystems in certain



locations.  However, I take issue with the Spenglerian-like view that




offshore fixed platform oil developments must invariably be inimical to



the maintenance of marine fisheries or marine ecosystems in general.  It




has been demonstrated on many stationary drilling  and pumping platforms




that scrupulously observed safety practices utilizing currently available



technology can protect the marine sports and commercial fisheries in those



areas.





     The offshore oil development versus commercial fishery argument ty-



pifies a rather tendentious and sometimes  sanctimonious environmentalist




handwringing.  This attitude handicaps objective and constructive
                                  206

-------
cooperation among the principal sectors of our society towards protecting



the natural environment without eroding the quality of life of man.





     In my view, the competitive pressures on the world's arable lands



causing their removal from agricultural production would have been much



more supportive of Woodwell's thesis.  While a relatively small percent-



age of the world's population is dependent upon marine fisheries for its



principal source of protein, the vast majority of the peoples of the



world are completely dependent upon the products of agriculture (much of



it imported) for their survival.  The Arab oil embargo, followed by the



OPEC quadrupling of oil prices, have had devastating effects on both



agricultural and fishery economies of many of the nations of the world.



It is not easy for a developing nation to sustain a rapidly growing pop-



ulation with a "two-mule" agriculture or a "sailboat" fishery.   A rich



commercial fishery which cannot be fished because the fishermen are



unable to pay the high price for oil is of no benefit from a practical



point of view to a protein deficient population.   Thus, while one may



agree with Woodwell's ultimate goal, support for his thesis is  eroded by



the doubtful validity of his supporting illustration.





     Dr.  Woodwell's proposal, presaged by the title of his paper "Re-



search for Regulators," reminds one of the comment attributed to the



distinguished scholar,  Sir Ritchie Calder, to the effect that science



yields knowledge,  not wisdom.  Wisdom derives from knowledge tempered



with judgment.   One might add that since sound judgment frequently de-



rives from experience,  one might assume that Dr.  Woodwell's experience



with regulatory  agencies has been rather limited.   His notion that the



Environmental Protection Agency would be the appropriate agency for



sponsoring basic research needed to preserve ".  .  .  . the earth's basic



chemical  and biotic patterns," is naive in my opinion.   One does not



subtract  from the  Environmental Protection Agency's well deserved credit




for sponsoring this symposium,  by taking exception to Dr.  Woodwell's






                                   207

-------
proposal to assign to it a national research responsibility, the imple-




mentation of which could exceed the capabilities and resources of all of




the civilian Federal R&D agencies lumped together.





     If the achievement of Dr.  Woodwell's ultimate goal is as important




for the future of mankind as I  believe it to be, then the knowledge re-



quired to achieve that goal must perforce derive from a wide variety of




basic and applied research investigations,  many of them seemingly un-




related.  The identification of research objectives, as well as the



selection of the requisite cadre of competent scientists and technolo-




gists from the natural and social science disciplines will require a




capability for research program planning and administration that may well




extend beyond the available resources in the oldline and experienced,



R&D agencies like NSF, NIH, and ONR;  much less a small, albeit capable



R&D unit within a single, mission oriented  regulatory agency like EPA.





     Perhaps the most prescient of Dr.  Woodwell's views is his assertion



that "The basic resource in support of human activities is carbon fixed



in photosynthesis and made available in various forms to man.  There is



abundant evidence that the world carbon budget is being affected grossly



by human activities."  The validation of that assertion and the means to



minimize and perhaps eliminate  man's adverse impacts on the global car-



bon budget merits the highest priority attention from legislative and



executive branch leaders, and certainly deserves both the development of




a unified national policy and the coordinated mobilization of our national



intellectual and material resources.   Anything less than a carefully or-



chestrated national program of  research and development cannot do justice




to our ultimate goal (so perceptively presented by Dr.  Woodwell) of pro-




tecting the life support capacities of our global environment while at



the same time delivering the necessities and amenities which in the




aggregate add the dimension of  quality to the human experience.  Cer-




tainly Dr. Woodwell's thesis deserves more than any single regulatory



agency could possibly deliver.



                                  208

-------
 RESEARCH NEEDS




FIFTH VIEWPOINT

-------
             SCARCITY, GEOPOLITICS, AND RESOURCE MANAGEMENT




                             John Zierold








Overview





     The United States and the entire world are in the midst of sudden




transformations that have led to the most massive shift of capital wealth




in the history of mankind.  It is a situation which has led to a multi-




plicity of crises with which the industrialized nations as well as the




underdeveloped countries cannot cope.





     The result of the energy crisis, brought about by the oil embargo,




has been the imminent prospect of starvation for millions in India,




Sahel, West Africa, and Latin America.  The energy crisis and the world




food crisis bring the greatest challenge to this country it has yet  faced,




and will bring about discontinuity in resource management whether we like




it or not.   Actions taken by the other nations will affect us to an  ex-




tent greater than we have anticipated and choices will be forced upon us




despite our unwillingness to acknowledge their existence.







Possible Impacts





     The world food crisis is really the sum of many crises:   the energy




crisis,  the population crisis, the urbanization crisis, and,  most criti-




cal of all, the policy crisis.





     The population growth rate worldwide is 2 percent per annum,  which




means a  doubling time of approximately 35 years.  Thus, shortly after




the year 2000 there will be 6 billion inhabitants to be fed,  employed,




and governed.   That figure is not the top of speculative conjecture, but,




in fact  an  ineluctable mathematical certainty.





                                  211

-------
     There is serious doubt that all  these billions can be properly




nourished,let alone saved from famine.   With the fourfold increase in




the price of petroleum—soon to be bumped upwards again—it is clear



that countries like India and Bangladesh have been priced out of the




fertilizer market,  which seriously hampers their food production.   The




same is true for many other countries too numerous to list.





     How to deal with this awesome spectre is beyond the comprehension




of virtually everyone.  Yet it is a crisis that will not go away and one




for which this country and all other countries must prepare with the




least possible delay.





     Some, like Professor Garrett Hardin, may argue for the adoption of




lifeboat ethics, by which they mean that we must resist our humanitarian



impulses and allow  the starving to perish—in order that they do not re-




produce and therefore create famine and death of even greater magnitude



in the decades to come.  It is a seductive theory for the affluent na-




tions, which can cool down the fever of their conscience through the



ministrations of situational ethics.   But the hard, bitter reality is



that we cannot sail Professor Hardin's lifeboat unmolested through a sea



teeming with people who wish to climb aboard.  In point of fact, Hardin's



metaphor is ill chosen.  The better comparison is a long train with one




firstclass carriage—in which the rich nations dine on the most lavish



provender—and a hundred cattle cars crowded with the hungry who at any



moment may move up to the firstclass carriage and take it over.






Possible Policy Responses





     Assuming that the United States were to adopt the lifeboat ethic




as the linchpin of its foreign policy, and assuming further that other




rich nations did the same, then we would see before long the rise of




iron governments in the third world:   elite coalitions of military and



civilian interests based, probably, on either the Red Chinese or






                                  212

-------
Brazilian model.  Wars of redistribution or forced migration, nuclear




blackmail for a share of the world's food and other  resources would be



all too likely an outcome.





     This scenario must surely be  evident to those who compose white



papers deep in the recesses of the Pentagon and the  State Department:



those experts who now are fumbling with such mercurial policy questions



as how to ameliorate energy shortages through energy independence in



this country, and how to frustrate Persian Gulf hopes to extort foreign



policy decisions from our allies in Western Europe and elsewhere.





     One possibility under consideration must certainly be the large



scale extraction and use of shale oil and coal.  With some 300 years of



coal reserves, the production of petroleum substitutes for use here and



for the supply of our allies to insulate them from the harsh winds of



embargo, must certainly be seen as a tempting solution to impending



disaster.





     The nation that can export energy and food will exert its logic on



other governments in a way enormously more effective than the use of



armaments in the post World War II period.






Environmental Consequences





     The impact of strip mining the Great Plains for coal,  pulverizing



the Rockies for shale oil,  and scaling ever upwards highly mechanized



fertilizer and energy intensive agriculture,  suggests the possibility



of very grave consequences indeed.   To pursue such a course of action



carries with it the possibility that we will confront biological  and



physical laws under the harshest and most punitive of terms for the




loser.





    All this suggests that we must begin now to formulate research pri-



orities that reduce the enormity of these impending problems.  Research
                                  213

-------
policies properly drawn will not stultify economic growth, but enhance



it.  The late 1970s and the decade of the 80s will see the emergence of



a vast and profitable new industry:   how to make sense out of change.






Suggested Research Programs





     Our view of the future is too often based upon a body of conven-



tional wisdom, but that orthodoxy is useful only under trouble-free



scenarios; i.e., so long as there are no factors inducing major system



breaks—discontinuities caused by such phenomena as resource limitations,



market saturation, or a slow response to crisis by a rigid bureaucracy.



In essence, anything that has not happened in the past is not accounted



for in the conceptual models based upon the conventional wisdom.  As a



result, as a harbinger of the future, conventional wisdom has been shown



to be no more accurate in anticipating the current economic difficulties



than it was in predicting or projecting the impacts of the energy crisis.





     It is clear, therefore, that to more accurately predict the future



we must understand the interrelationships and trends that now shape it.





     Cheap energy has fostered a throw-away society.  As the cost of



energy increases, the social and economic impacts may cause significant



changes in historic trends.  Labor-intensive, as opposed to energy-



intensive industries will be encouraged and a society will evolve that



stresses reusability as opposed to discard.  These changes in trends can



be called system breaks, and they are the surprises in the future unan-



ticipated by practitioners of conventional wisdom.






     Environmental Impacts and Economies of Urban Densities





     The nation can no longer afford sprawl.  In a recent study, the



Council on Environmental Quality compared the costs of low-density



sprawl with those of high density.   It found that sprav/ling communities
                                  214

-------
use up to 44 percent more energy and 35 percent more water, while high-



density communities produce 45 percent less air pollution.





     Largely as a result of private auto-intensive transportation sys-



tems, U.S. urban centers have expanded as sprawling low-density suburban



areas.  It has recently been widely recognized that this low-density



sprawl has caused air pollution, consumed vast quantities of prime agri-



cultural land, and helped bring about the energy crunch.  As a result,



recent efforts in some sectors have been aimed at reducing sprawl and



promoting greater densities.





     Containment of the city is an economic imperative.  Consider the



distribution of water.  Mr. Gordon spoke about extrapolating the forces



at work for greater and greater consumption; and that the doubling of



the world's population—if people were to exist at our levels of con-



sumption—would mean before long that the planet would be virtually



picked clean of its resources.





     If one doubles peoples' water supply by doubling the service area,



at constant density, it is necessary to accept the cost of doubling pipe



mileage, the cross-section of the old system, and upgrading pipe joints



to hold extra pressure.  And that is but one feature of the economies of



density.





     In some circumstances, however, greater numbers can be accommodated



without doubling.   If the demand for water doubles within a fixed serv-



ice area,  it is not necessary to double all the service facilities.   It



is probable that it would only be necessary to expand all pipe diameters —



not by double, but by the square root of two, since—as mathematicians



tell us—cross-sections increase with the square of the radius.





     On the other hand, the environmental effects of increased urban



densities  are not  obvious.   It is clear that with less sprawl, per capita



miles driven should be reduced,  resulting in less per capita air pollutant






                                  215

-------
generation.  However;  with the increased density, the concentration of




air pollutants may,  in fact,  increase.   Although less energy would be




used for transportation,  denser urban areas may be more energy intensive



to provide for cooling (due to urban heat island effects)  and for high-




rise living if that  is the trend.   It may be necessary to  provide for



more vegetation and  green areas as sinks for air pollutants and as cli-




mate moderators.






     Environmental Impacts of Recovering Subeconomic Deposits





     Many estimates  have  been developed of world reserves  of various



materials, known deposits recoverable with current technology and at




current costs.  Other  estimates consider so-called hypothetical and



speculative deposits—supplies occurring in lesser concentrations, in



more remote locations/depths  and of lesser known quantities.  These de-



posits are cited as  evidence  of no serious material shortage problems.




However, it should be  recognized that all other than proved resources



require significant  increases in expenditures (including operating costs,



capital investment,  energy costs,  and technology improvement) to make



recovery of these resources feasible.  In addition, it is  also essential



to consider the potentially huge environmental impact of recovering ma-




terials in small concentrations from isolated or environmentally sensi-



tive locations.  Taken together, such considerations may put many sup-



posed material deposits out of reach.





     Research programs should be formulated to identify existing quan-



tities of subeconomic  deposits of critical materials.  The locations and




physical conditions  of these  deposits should be determined.  Finally,




the environmental impacts of  recovering these deposits should be



evaluated.
                                  216

-------
     Environmental Costs of Mineral Extraction and Processing





     In the extraction, transportation, processing, use, and disposition



of goods and materials, the protection of the environment—especially air



and water—has historically been largely ignored.  Our market system that



allocates the use of material resources by putting prices on them has



traditionally regarded environmental resources as free goods; they have



customarily not been written into the equation for the cost of producing



goods and services, and have therefore not been reflected in the prices



consumers have paid.  Unless the true costs of commodities are reflected



in their prices, there is a tendency to over-consume certain materials



or to delay development of substitutes when such development is in the



public interest.  A related example is the fact that cost/benefit analy-



ses of highway systems rarely if ever include the costs of air pollution



attributable to cars.  These costs are borne separately by other agencies



(e.g., EPA)  or by consumers through increased health care costs.





     These considerations are of special relevance in the case of min-



erals.  Improper pricing policies can result in the unnecessary depletion



of strategic minerals.






     Preservation of Prime Agricultural Lands





     Worldwide increases in food production have been obtained by the use



of high yield "green revolution" crop strains and the increased use of



fertilizers  and pesticides.  Green revolution crops are extremely fer-



tilizer sensitive—great quantities of fertilizer are required and the



use of lesser quantities results in smaller yields than would have been



achieved by  older,  unimproved strains.   In addition,  the newer improved



strains are  more susceptible to a greater variety of  pests.





     With the fourfold price increase in crude oil,  the supply of



petroleum-based fertilizers and pesticides has been put out of reach
                                  217

-------
of less-developed countries.   For every million tons of reduction in




fertilizer supply,  there is a corresponding 10-million-ton drop in grain




production in these countries.   Moreover,  the problems will become worse,




since a worldwide shortage of nitrogen-based fertilizers is likely to




occur over the next several decades because of the anticipated shortfall




of natural gas.





     Such developments will exert pressure on the use of more lands for



the production of lower yield and less energy-intensive crop strains.



However, significant quantities of prime agricultural lands are lost to




urbanization each year in the United States.   Preservation of these lands



will be essential as will be development of less petroleum-intensive means




to make these and other lands more productive.






     Preservation of Green Spaces Within Urban Areas





     With pressures for increased density within urban areas, the amount




of open space land preserved within urban regions may rapidly decrease.



There is growing evidence,  however,  that those lands serve important pur-




poses in urban regions.  They permit natural recharge of ground water



supplies (much development has occurred in prime recharge areas thus



exacerbating ground water depletion problems);  vegetation helps to save



energy by cooling areas (by transpiration),  while reducing dust and noise




pollution levels; vegetation has been shown to be an important element in




reducing concentrations of air pollutants since many plants naturally up-




take many air pollutants, e.g.,  sulfur dioxide,  nitrogen dioxide, and




ozone.  Furthermore, many urban areas include marsh lands, which have




been found to be of great value for tertiary wastewater treatment.  It



is important that these benefits be recognized by planners and policy-



makers so that provisions for the proper preservation of such lands be



undertaken before open space lands within urban areas are completely lost



to development.
                                  218

-------
                     REVIEW OF PAPER BY J.  ZIEROLD
                          Frank P, Sebastian
                        Envirotech Corporation
     I should like to go through John's  excellent paper commenting in
the areas where I feel I may have something to offer:  for instance, his
reference to nuclear blackmail for a share of the world's food and other
resources from such governments as his example of the People's Republic
of China (PRC).   I would add that, having had an opportunity to visit
the PRC in 1972 among the first 30 Americans who visited mainland China
after that 20-year gap, I learned two things that relate to the scenario
John drew out.  The Chinese say, contrary to what we and they learned in
school books, that they are self-sufficient in oil and are able to pro-
vide all their oil resources.1 In fact,  they are exporting oil to Japan
and possibly to other countries.

     Along with this, representatives of the PRC also reported that after
years,  decades,  generations of starvation they were now substantially
able to feed themselves.   My wife and I visited two of their communes—
one,  particularly,  outside Canton that was the county seat for 980,000
people.   It was  pointed out by commune leaders that following the PRC's
takeover of the  government 20 years ago a decision was made to augment
the reuse of nightsoil, or the recycle of waste material,  which they had
been  practicing  for centuries, by using chemical fertilizer.   Later I
learned  from U.S.  Commerce Department reports that the exportation of
Japanese chemical  fertilizer to the Chinese was really the basis for the
rapid growth of  the Japanese fertilizer industry following World War II.
The Chinese imported vast  quantities of chemical fertilizer,  increased
their food  production,  and then embarked on a program of building

                                  219

-------
fertilizer plants in the communes.   In the communes we visited, there




were fertilizer plants of various sizes that were much smaller than any-



thing we would consider building in the United States today.





     The point I want to make is that it was only through the addition of




chemical fertilizer that the Chinese were able to increase their food



production and, since 1970,  to be self-sufficient.   In one brigade at




Tung Fan County they pointed to a granary of rice and said,  "We are no



longer at the peril of the drought  or flood; we have several years' sup-




ply of grain and are able to sell some of our production."





     So hopefully in other lesser developed countries there is some




parallel opportunity for improvement in food production that will help



reduce the number of people trying  to get on John's proverbial lifeboat.





     In connection with environmental consequences, John states that re-




search policies, properly drawn,  will not stultify  economic growth but



enhance it,  and with that I  most heartily agree.   I think Mr.  Ruckelshaus



in his excellent paper set the stage for this when  he talked about having



four times as many economists in his agency as he had ecologists.   It is



in this arena that the studies on the benefits of pollution cleanup and




the elimination of damages from pollution are really critical economic



and social factors.  I am referring to damages created from pollution



that are being suffered by us individually,  and are being paid for by us



individually.  We sorely need more  research on these social  costs,  as




well as on the extent to which air  and water pollution cleanup will eli-




minate damages so that the figures  will be less controversial and we can



have broader support of them.





     These facts are just emerging  in the United  States and  are not gen-




erally recognized.   However,  England was the first  country to take strin-




gent action  on a national pollution problem and reap the national benefits,
                                  220

-------
     Let me shift the subject to air pollution and draw on the message

from President Nixon to the Congress to illustrate:

          "in London in December 1952 an air pollution episode
          lasted five days and was associated with 4,000 excess
          deaths.  During the episode 1,100 patients per day,
          or 48 percent above normal, were admitted to the
          hospitals of London."

     I would like to add that four years later stringent air pollution

control legislation was passed in England, but it was not until 14 years

later that tangible benefits were broadly reported.  Sunshine increased

over 50 percent in London in December, infamous London fogs disappeared,

and rare birds—the snow bunting, the hoopoe, and the great northern

diver—have reappeared.  House martins have returned to nest near Prim-

rose Hill after an 80-year absence.  Though no estimate is available,

substantial savings can be expected in reduction of the $700 million of

annual damages from air pollution.  The national cost of controls was

$1 billion over 10 years.3

     Table 1 shows 1972 EPA figures for water pollution;  it indicates

that cleanup yields some overall savings.   The benefits of water pollu-

tion cleanup can be observed this way:  that the damages throughout  the

United States were estimated at about $12.8 billion.   The savings from

cleaning up that water were estimated at about $11.5 billion,  whereas

the costs in that level of cleanup were only about $6.3 billion,  giving

a net savings of $5.2 billion.3

     In the air sector, we have a somewhat similar equation.   The damages

were estimated at $16.1 billion,  the savings through cleanup were $10.7

billion.   The cleanup costs at that time were estimated to be less than

$4 billion,  giving a net savings of about $6.8 billion.  I believe those
                                                                  o
figures include something like $6 billion a year for health costs.

Subsequent reports estimate that the cost  of treating environmentally

caused  illnesses amounts to something over $30 billion a  year.    There

                                 221

-------
is, thus, a huge potential increase in the savings figure if those medi-

cal figures are correct.   Of course,  here is an area that I am suggesting

needs a great deal of research attention to improve the accuracy of the

savings figures so that they can be used with a greater degree of con-

fidence.



                                Table 1

                  BENEFITS OF WATER POLLUTION CLEANUP


                                      Annual Amounts
                                   All USA        Per Family
            1972 damages        $12.8 billion        $213
            Cleanup savings     $11.5 billion        $192
            Cleanup costs       $ 6.3 billion        $105
            Net savings         $ 5.2 billion        $ 87
                   BENEFITS OF AIR POLLUTION CLEANUP
                                      Annual  Amounts
                                   All  USA        Per Family

            1972 damages        $16.1 billion        $268
            Cleanup savings     $10.7 billion        $178
            Cleanup costs       $ 3.9 billion        $ 65
            Net savings         $ 6.8 billion        $113
     As a result of the end of cheap  energy,  John pointed out,  there
will be an era where labor-intensive  as  opposed  to energy-intensive in-
dustries will be encouraged.   Certainly,  a  reevaluation must take place.
However, our societies individually will  reorder their priorities and
may not go all the way.  For example,  this  past  Sunday when I was in
Athens, the traffic jam at 10:00 o'clock in the  morning was enormous.

                                  222

-------
The cab driver explained that it was hot and  the Athenians were going to



the beach.  In talking about other  things we  learned later that the price



of gasoline was $3.00 a gallon.  By our normal  logic, we would think that



when the price reached $3.00 a gallon  for gas we would find some other



way to get to the beach besides using  our individual automobiles.  But



that does not seem to be the case in Greece, which is already facing



these kinds of problems.





     Rather than totally labor-intensive industry being developed, I



would think that improved efficiency through  improved technology offers



an intermediate ground and will present great opportunity for R&D ac-



tivities.





     With regard to the problems and opportunities in R&D for increased



water demand,  as pointed out by John Zierold, I think here a partial



technical answer lies in the field of  water reuse.  The incremental cost



of producing reusable water is less in many cases than the costs of



water from new sources.   The incremental cost will narrow further as the



1983 effluent  standards are met.  Another benefit to figure into the



equation is the elimination of the cost of damage from polluted water,



as well as a huge plus from the value  of the reclaimed water!





     To further illustrate, there are  economic advantages to upgrading



existing plants to produce high quality effluent suitable for reuse.



The incremental cost to  achieve high quality water over and above second-



ary effluent is shown in Figure 1.   Secondary treatment is assumed as the



base standard.   The tertiary treatment incremental costs are for upgrad-



ing secondary  treatment  processes to facilities that would produce an



effluent complying with  WHO or in laboratory tests with USPHS standards.



(The USPHS standards do  not apply to reclaimed water even though the



water meets  the required laboratory tests.)   The assumed tertiary treat-



ment consists of  lime clarification, filtration, and carbon adsorption,
                                  223

-------
as well as reclamation and reuse of the lime and carbon, and thus has




favorable environmental impact.





     Given the incremental cost to produce a reusable quality water in




most existing plants,  the potential net benefit of this water can be



estimated.  This benefit is the difference between the present market



value of tap water and the incremental cost of producing the tap water




from secondary effluent (Figure 1).





     The present market values for tap water vary widely across the




United States.  For example,  in the San Francisco Bay Area, tap water



costs range from about $0.18  to $0.38/1,000 gal ($0.048 to $0.10/m3),




and price increases have been reported since 1972 and to 1975.   Figure 2



shows the estimated net potential benefit of water reclamation that can



be realized by adding tertiary treatment to a conventional plant.





     Any projected cost for increased supply of tap water (for a given




flow) that lies above the marginal cost curve will realize a benefit for



reuse.  For example, if an average cost of tap water is assumed to be



$0.25/1,000 gal ($0.066/m3),  the benefit of reclaiming wastewater with



tertiary treatment would range from $0.03/1,000 gal ($0.008/m3)  at 10



mgd  (37,900 m3/day) to $0.12/1,000 gal ($0.032/m3)  at 100 mgd (379,000




irrVday) .   These benefit statistics indicate that water reuse offers a



unique opportunity not only to eliminate pollution but also to reuse a



finite,  limited resource economically.





     Not only will water reuse make good economic sense in many cases,




but dwindling freshwater supplies for agricultural, industrial,  and muni-



cipal needs will make it a necessity in the future.  In 1957 the total




freshwater use in the United  States began to exceed the dependable sup-




ply.  The gross water deficit is expected to increase for the foreseeable




future,  far outstretching the total supply capable of development by the



year 2000.  The only way to overcome the deficit is through a greater



reliance on water reuse.




                                  224

-------
o
o>
in
8
!5
LU
     40
     30
20
      10
 INCREMENTAL COST'
•JOF REUSABLE WATER
               20      40      60      80

                 PLANT SIZE-mil. gal./day
                                                 SECONDARY
                                                 AND TERTIARY
                                           SECONDARY
                                         100
    Note:  January 1971 cost (6%, 25 yr.) amortization included
    FIGURE I. COST OF CONVENTIONAL AND ADVANCED
             TREATMENT OF WA STEW ATE R
                        225

-------
    40
    30
o
o

2   20

EC
UJ
O-
z
LJ

0   10
INCREMENTAL COST OF

  REUSABLE WATER
               20        40       60        80


                     PLANT SIZE-mil. gal./day
                                   100
       FIGURE 2. POTENTIAL BENEFIT OF WATER REUSE
                             226

-------
     What is the problem with this scenario?  We have not done the neces-



sary health effects R&D to be sure that the reclaimed water can be cut



into the tap supply.  Also, the evaluation of any psychological consid-



erations should be undertaken to obtain all the necessary answers to per-



mit the safe and widespread use of reclaimed water.





     A great deal of effort needs to be put forward in sounding out the



true public attitudes toward the direct reuse of water.  I think the per-



ceived public attitude is that the public is unwilling to come to grips



with reclaimed water.  However, a U.S. government survey of 155 cities



with populations over 25,000 using surface water showed that 145 of them



have some raw waste in the water supply and up to 17 to 18.5 percent raw



waste in their source of water in the dry season.  Cleveland,  Ohio gets



its drinking water from Lake Erie, which is known to contain industrial



and municipal wastes.  London obtains about one-fifth of its metropolitan



drinking water supply from the River Lee, 10 miles (16.1 km) downstream



from the Rye Meads Treatment Plant, the highest quality wastewater treat-



ment plant in the United Kingdom.  Paris draws its tap water from the



River Seine, but I am told that France is a bottled water society.





     A recent U.S. Public Health Service (USPHS)6 survey of community



water supply systems showed that 41 percent of the systems, serving one-



third of the study population, delivered water with a quality  lower than



the effluent from some of the advanced waste treatment plants  to be dis-



cussed.  Projected nationally, this is equal to about 50 million people



in the United States drinking water of a quality lower than that pro-




duced from an advanced waste treatment plant.





     Most recently,  of course, the great conduit between dirty water and




clean water has come to light in terms of the New Orleans tap  water re-



port, and I suggest that it would be a great contribution to determine




what indeed the public attitudes are toward direct reuse of water and
                                  227

-------
make the additional R&D necessary to determine the long-range health ef-




fects from such use.





     I should mention that there is one plant that some of you know has




existed since 1967,7  and that is directly recycling sewage into its tap



water supply.  There was no public outcry when the plant was turned on.




I visited the plant—in Windhoek, Namibia—in 1969; I'll always remember



the moment of truth when my daughter poked her head out of the bathroom



with a toothbrush in her hand,  saying,  "is it safe to use the water?"  I




knew that 30 percent of the water supply came directly from the sewage




treatment plant.   But they had  done all of the reliability, viral,  and




epidemicological  studies that showed,  as we also found, it is safe.





     However, this brings up a  curious  facet about technology.   The tech-




nology used in Windhoek to treat the water is not greatly dissimilar from



that used at the  Lake Tahoe,  California Water Reclamation Plant, but their



technicians were  not sure that  the technology existed to economically re-




generate the activated carbon used in one of the process steps.   So they



just spread the spent, expensive material on the ground.  From experience



in the United States  we knew that one could economically regenerate car-



bon and reuse it  on site.   Conversely,  we are not sure one can safely



drink the water.   So  we throw away the  water!





     I should like to cite some specific examples of the state of the



technology; i.e.,  the technology on which the equipment manufacturers



are bidding,  and  indeed guaranteeing performance today without waiting



for any additional R&D output.





     I suggest that in developing future R&.D programs,  serious consider-



ation should  be given to such existing  technology as that in operation




at the South Tahoe Water Reclamation Plant which is one of the most ad-




vanced plants in  the United States.  This 7.5-mgd plant, as you undoubt-




edly know, has been operating since 1967 and has been converting municipal
                                  228

-------
sewage to a water that will meet laboratory tests for drinking water;



it has not failed to meet its standard for the full period of its opera-



tion.   Please note that I am not saying that this water can be connected



directly to the U.S. tap water supply, but it will  meet laboratory tests



for drinking water,  and, as we all are now aware from recent reports on



contaminants, much of the surface water in our tap supplies today does



contain elements of sewage effluent that have not been anywhere near as



highly treated as the Tahoe wastewater.





     A key aspect of this most advanced plant is the sludge processing



and handling, for as you increase the level of pollutants removed you in-



crease the amount of sludge generated.  The Tahoe plant received a gen-



erous amount of federal funding for the liquid stage but it was not until



the Clean Water Restoration Act of 1966 was passed in December of that



year,  providing R&D funds, that sufficient money was available to install



the solids handling and processing system.  Tahoe received one of the



very first R&D grants under the 1966 Act for over $1 million to demon-



strate an incineration/reclamation process that would reclaim the treat-



ment chemicals—lime, in this case—for on-site reuse.





     It is pertinent to my point that although this sludge project was



fully funded by the federal government as an R&D project the successful



equipment bidder had to guarantee the performance of this equipment,  thus



in effect guaranteeing the results of an R&D program.  The results spe-



cified were achieved.  Thus,  for the first time it was  demonstrated that



a complete environmentally compatible wastewater treatment plant could



make a drinkable quality water from sewage, reclaiming  chemicals on site,



and converting all residue to a sterile ash that, as I  shall mention




later,  has some other resource reclamation potentials.





     You may be wondering:  "What about the impact of the incineration




reclamation process  on the pristine air quality in the  Lake Tahoe area?
                                  229

-------
The environmental impact on the air quality is nil:   there is no visible



plume and the highly cleansed exhaust gases are recirculated through




partially treated waters at one stage of the process to reclaim the car-




bon dioxide for reuse in the process.





     Both of these facilities involve conventional biological treatment




with a tertiary physical chemical treatment facility added.   Since these



plants were built there have also been other industry and government de-




velopments in physical chemical treatment,  commonly called PCT processes,



which are of great significance.   In July 1971 the EPA announced its



lime/activated carbon physical chemical process,  including on-site lime



and carbon reclamation through high temperature thermal processes.





     My company has also developed somewhat similar PCT processes that




produce a product water comparable to Tahoe quality water.  A further



step of development in sludge processing beyond that achieved at Tahoe




has been attained which combines  in a patented process the two steps of



lime recovery and incineration into one step utilizing the fuel value of



the sludge as a partial source of fuel to reclaim the lime for on-site



reuse.  Several plants utilizing  these PCT  processes are currently under



construction involving many millions of dollars of EPA construction grant



support.





     Another industry development,  similar  to one in the current EPA R&D




budget, is that of energy reclamation from  sewage plants.   Although I




have already mentioned reclamation of the fuel value of sewage sludge to




reclaim chemicals on-site for reuse, this has been taken a step further



in three EPA-funded municipal plants currently under construction involv-




ing the use of third-generation multiple-hearth furnace systems called



Closed Loop Energy Systems (Figure 3).  In  these systems a sludge heat



treatment step is installed to break loose  the water bound in the bio-




logical cells to enable normal dewatering equipment (vacuum filters or
                                  230

-------
                                   REACTOR
                DECANT TANK

                     VACUUM FILTER
                                       WASTE HEAT BOILER
         SCUM CONCENTRATOR
MULTIPLE HEARTH
   FURNACE
FIGURE 3.  CLOSED ENERGY LOOP, SLUDGE HANDLING SYSTEMS
          INCORPORATES HEAT TREATMENT, INCINERATION,
          AND HEAT RECOVERY
                         231

-------
centrifuges)  to be used  to  obtain a  250  percent  increase in the normal

solids content of the sludge.   This  brings  the sludge to a  fuel value

approximately equal to that of  soft  coal.   The heat-treated sludge is

then processed through a similar  but differently designed furnace to

convert itself to a sterile, potentially useful  ash without the need  for

auxiliary operating fuels and with sufficient excess heat reclaimed to

provide process heat and steam  at the treatment  plant.

     Because of the often prevalent  view of the  strong need for more

sludge processing technology, you must be wondering about the impact
upon air quality of these incineration/reclamation  units.   Thanks to  both

EPA and industry-sponsored  R&.D  activities in detailed analyses of the
exhaust gases, the heretofore unknown environmental benefits of these

processes have recently  been discovered.  Several points are worth

noting:

     (1)   These combustion  units  will meet  the new  air quality standards
          under the Clean Air Act.

     (2)   The exhaust gases have  been ruled by one  of the most stringent
          air pollution  control agencies in the  United States, the San
          Francisco Bay  Area Air  Pollution  Control  District, to have  an
          insignificant  impact  on air quality.

     (3)   Combustion decomposes worrisome pesticides,  such  as DDT and
          2,4,5-T,  that  may be  contained in the  sludge at normal op-
          erating temperatures  at no extra  cost,  and such materials
          are not contained in  the exhaust  air or in the ash product.

     (4)   Destroyed in the  process are polychlorinated biphenyls (or
          PCBs),  which have been  determined by the  EPA to be the most
          persisent of the  chlorinated hydrocarbon  group found in sludge.
          In fact,  based on a search of  the literature,  it  would appear
          the only way that PCBs  are being  removed  from our environment
          once they are  introduced is through modern sludge incineration
          as employed at wastewater  treatment plants.
          Although EPA research efforts  of  1971  and 1972 were uncertain
          as to the fate of incinerated  PCBs, independent laboratory  tests
          sponsored by private  industry  showed that PCBs and most of  the

                                  232

-------
          other substances on EPA's proposed toxic chemicals list were
          destroyed under normal operating temperatures.  EPA-sponsored
          tests in 1974 confirmed these 1972 data, showing the complete
          decomposition of DDT and 2,4,5-T.

     (5)  These systems control heavy metals contained in sludge.  Mer-
          cury in the EPA proposed toxic substances list was found, con-
          trary to conventional thinking, to be controlled.  From 83 per-
          cent to 96 percent of the trace amounts of mercury normally
          found in sludge is removed from the exhaust gases in two dif-
          ferent multiple-hearth installations.  These studies were
          sponsored by the EPA air quality group at Research Triangle
          Park.

     (6)  These systems employ recovery processes to reclaim both lime
          and carbon dioxide in advanced PCT plants.

     (7)  They create a product—ash—that is potentially useful as a
          quasi-fertilizer because it normally contains 6 percent to
          15 percent phosphate (Table 2).  Over 50,000 tons of sludge
          ash have been used experimentally in Japan as a quasi-
          fertilizer and deserve more R&D consideration.  Sludge ash
          is purified of PCBs and pesticides and, because the nutrients
          are more concentrated, has a potential value of $48.00 per
          ton—four times that of wet sludge (Figure 4).

     To bring the air quality impact of advanced sludge combustion sys-

tems into perspective and to furnish the basis for future R&D needs,  it

would be helpful to compare automobile pollution emissions with exhaust

emissions from sludge combustion equipment.  When comparing one average

automobile,  which reportedly travels 12 miles per day,  against the air
quality impact from sludge combustion on a per capita basis,  we find that

sludge combustion is about equivalent to burning one ounce of gasoline in

an automobile.   With sludge combustion, however, we are removing harmful

chemicals from the environment and  reclaiming increasingly precious re-

sources—water,  lime,  carbon, and others.  A detailed comparison of these

emissions is shown in Figure 5.

     What about the costs of this treatment technology?  In the GAO re-

port to the  Congress on EPA R&D last year,  it was stated that "The high

                                   233

-------
cost of sludge handling and disposal is well recognized."  Well, let's
take a look at those costs.


                                Table 2

             TYPICAL ANALYSIS OF ASH FROM TERTIARY QUALITY
                   ADVANCED WASTE TREATMENT SYSTEM

                                                Percent of Total



Silica (SiOa)
Alumina (A1203)
Iron oxide (Feg03)
Magnesium oxide (MgO)
Total calcium oxide (CaO)
Available (free) calcium oxide (CaO)
Sodium (Na)
Potassium (K)
Boron (B)
Phosphorus pentoxide (P205)
Sulfate ion (S04)
Loss on ignition
Sample 1
Lake Tahoe
11/19/69
23.85
16.34
3.44
2.12
29.76
1.16
0.73
0.14
0.02
6.87
2.79
2.59
Sample 2
Lake Tahoe
11/25/69
23.75
22.10
2.65
2.17
24.47
1.37
0.35
0.11
0.02
15.35
2.84
2.24
     At the Tahoe plant,  sludge incineration costs amount to one-sixth
of the total plant operating and amortization costs,  or about $1.74 per
capita per year.   Fuel  costs and labor and  material costs have gone up
sharply since these data  were developed,  but as  mentioned earlier the
new Closed Loop Energy  Systems furnaces eliminate the need for auxiliary
operating fuel.  For cities  of one  million  population,  Closed Energy Loop
Systems cost about 38
-------
to
CO
en
              804
             60
v*
 i
 
-------
SLUDGE FURNACE vs. AUTOMOBILE
HYDROCARBON EMISSIONS
PER PERSON PER DAY
1970 ACTU
35 1 glam
*•**•
'Based on 12 mile

AUTOMOBILE EXHAUST EM 5SIONS BSP MULTIPLE HEARTH
Grams pei mile i 12 m lei' Grim* par day "
40 B grams 4 S grams 019 grami
per day ' -Batad on 0 2 Ibs dry iludg*
solid, per day per p*>aon

SLUDGE FURNACE vs. AUTOMOBILE
CARBON MONOXIDE EMISSIONS
PER PERSON PER DAY

1970 ACTU*
564 grami
•BaMdon 12 mil**
Hal: EPA 4/12/71

1972 STANDARDS ! 1975 STANDARDS FU™*CE EM.SSIONS
Gram, per mlto . 12 milW Grami p., day ' '
4CB grami 40,8 B'ami 057 grami
|
P*' dl> "Bawd m 0.2 Iba. dry aludg*
•vHBflfl ol 60 U.S. aulo prolotypM. tolld' P" dl" f*1 P*™"1
SLUDGE FURNACE vs. AUTOMOBILE
NITROGEN OXIDE EMISSIONS
PER PERSON PER DAY
1
1170 ACTUA
4B 2 gram.
l>a*a>
*B*M<) on 11 milmt
R«f EPA 4/13/7
AUTOMOBILE EXHAUST EMISSIONS BSP MULTIPLE HEARTH
1972 STANDARDS | 1976 STANDARDS I^NACE LMiettlUHa
Grami par mlto » IS miiw QrBmi p,, day . .
36 0 gram* 4.8 grimi 0.29 grami
pw day " B*Md on 0 2 lb» dry aludfl*
•olkl* p*> d*y p«f pwaon
a**rag« ol 60 U S aulo pfOlot»p*»



SLUDGE FURNACE vs. AUTOMOBILE
HYDROCARBON EMISSIONS
1970 COMPARATIVE RATIO 1975 COMPARATIVE RATIO
29OO:1

250:1
S. •*
AUTOMOBILE SLUDGE FURNACE AUTOMOBILE SLUDGE FUBNACE
SLUDGE FURNACE vs. AUTOMOBILE
CARBON MONOXIDE EMISSIONS
1970 COMPARATIVE RATIO
10,6OO: 1
_ fJB^I
1975 COMPARATIVE RATIO
700:1
AUTOMOBILE SLUDGE FURNACE AUTOMOBILE SLUDGE FURNACE
SLUDGE FURNACE vs. AUTOMOBILE
NITROGEN OXIDE EMISSIONS
1970 COMPARATIVE RATIO
170:1
1976 COMPARATIVE RATIO
16:1
I
AUTOMOBILE SLUDGE FURNACE AUTOMOBILE SLUDGE FURNACE
FIGURE 5. EMISSIONS OF SLUDGE FURNACE SYSTEM VS. AUTOMOBILE
                          236

-------
     For some years, systems have been operating in Europe that also use



shredded waste paper as an auxiliary support source of fuel.  However



when the price of waste paper went up recently, the source dried up and



created problems.  Obviously, availability is a potential limit to refuse



scrap paper systems.  A more reliable source of fuel would seem to be



that of the sludge itself since one is literally converting a "sow's ear



into a silk purse" on site, i.e., using the integral fuel value in the



sludge to purify itself.





     In the industrial sector, I should like to draw on a pulp and paper



industry example to illustrate the advanced technology available.   In



the already mentioned GAO report to the Congress last year,  it was esti-



mated that only 5 percent to 20 percent of the technology needed for zero



discharge was available as of June 1973.  As an indication of either tech-



nology overlooked or progress made since that time, I should like  to use



an example from the bleached pulp industry to show what can be done on



zero discharge.  Our firm, through its joint venture with a Canadian firm,



has successfully conducted pilot demonstration of a process for bleached



kraft mills which produces no contaminated liquid effluent from the plant.



It has just been announced that we are supplying Great Lakes Paper Com-



pany with the Erco-Envirotech Salt Recovery Process for a new 700-ton-



per-day bleached kraft mill at Thunder Bay, Ontario.





     In summary,  briefly,  some areas in which proven technology does



exist and is frequently overlooked are in the water pollution control



field.   Water reuse technology has proved its availability to the  point



where treated water will meet laboratory tests for drinking  water,  but



we need the additional  R&D on long-range health effects and  monitoring



systems to  be sure  that the water continues to meet standards.   Progress



is being made toward zero  pollution discharge requirements in the  paper




industry.
                                  237

-------
     There are also new developments in sludge processing technology




where sludge can be processed with insignificant  effects on air quality



and phosphate can be reclaimed as  an integral  part  of the process.





     There is a need for far more  R&D on  damage caused by pollution,




damage eliminated by cleanup,  pollutant related health effects,  and  the




utilization of sludge ash residues for their fertilizer value,  for both



wet sludge and ash.
                                 238

-------
                               REFERENCES


1.   F.  P.  Sebastian,  Jr.,  "Environmental Technology in Developing and
    Developed Nations," Uniting Nations for Biosurvival,  An  Interna-
    tional Symposium  sponsored by the National Wildlife Federation,
    Stockholm,  June 10-12,  1972.                                ~

2.   Ibid.

3.   T.  L.  Kimball,  "Hidden  Savings from a Cleaner America,"  National
    Wildlife Magazine (February-March 1972).

4.   F.  Green, Keynote Speech at ENVIRONMENT '73,  Office of  International
    Activities,  EPA,  presented at Sydney, Austrialia.

5.   "Studies Relating to Market Projections for Advanced  Waste Treatment,"
    U.S.  Department of Interior,  FWPCA,  WP-20-AWTR-17.

6.   "Community Water  Supply Study - Analysis  of National  Survey Findings,"
    USPHS,  NEW (July  1970).

7.   F.  P.  Sebastian,  "Tahoe and Windhoek:  Promise and Proof of Clean
    Water," Chemical  Engineering Progress Symposium Series,  1970.

8.   Statement of F. P.  Sebastian, Jr.,  at Hearings before the Subcommittee
    on  the Environment and  the Atmosphere of  the  Committee on Science and
    Technology,  U.S.  House  of Representatives, March 4-6, 1975.
                                  239

-------
  CONCLUSIONS




Kendall D. Moll

-------
                              CONCLUSIONS




                            Kendall D. Moll








    The systems viewpoint that permeates this proceedings is not quite




what one might expect in a discussion of environmental and resource




issues.  It is a social rather than a physical viewpoint, reflecting the




increased realization that EPA's responsibilities are basically social




even though they deal with physical systems.  Accordingly, EPA research




programs must be set in a socia-1 systems context.





    Lynton Caldwell points out in his paper that one cannot make a




reasonable listing of research priorities without a structure within




which to fit the various priorities.  Such a structure is shown in the




following illustration.  Its components are the same as the six themes




mentioned in the Summary.  These components describe a hierarchy of re-




search program areas organized partly by function, partly by the time




horizon of the research that is needed in that component, and partly by




the degree of specialization required.  All of the components are re-




lated to each other either directly or indirectly within the common




structure.





    The top box,  Environmental Systemic Interactions, represents the




ties required among systems that impact on the environment.   The defined




systems then provide the structure for describing lower level research




programs and for  using research results from the lower components.   Be-




cause of the large degree of abstraction of research dealing with inter-




actions and its  remoteness from direct applications, this component may




be considered  of  long-term research interest with payoffs that may take




10 years or more.
                                  243

-------
     RESEARCH THEMES
                                             LEAD TIMES
   RESOURCE USAGE
      PATTERNS
  APPLIED RESEARCH
   AND TECHNOLOGY
     DEVELOPMENT
                      ENVIRONMENTAL
                         SYSTEMIC
                       INTERACTIONS
  INCENTIVES
FOR CONTROLLING
 ENVIRONMENT
ENVIRONMENTAL
MONITORING AND
  ASSESSMENT
                    LONG TERM:
                    10 YEARS OR MORE
                    TO IMPLEMENT
INTERMEDIATE:
5 YEARS OR MORE
TO IMPLEMENT
SHORT TERM:
LESS THAN 5 YEARS
TO IMPLEMENT
FIGURE I.  HIERARCHY OF RESEARCH PRIORITIES
                     244

-------
    At the next lower level of the hierarchy,  reflecting more concrete



applications and a somewhat shorter period of  response, is the component



for Resource Usage Patterns.  Resource usage patterns describe activities



systems of a physically observable nature—such as the production and



consumption patterns of asbestos.  These patterns are necessary to gain



an appreciation of the material, operational,  and geographic nature of the



processes involved.





    Also at the intermediate level of response time is the third compo-



nent, Incentives for Control of Environment.   This subset of research



tasks is designed to provide answers to motivational problems involving



social and economic responses to environmental regulations.





    One of the short-term response categories, Critical Ecological Prob-



lems, has become more prominent as a formal research objective in recent



years because of accumulating evidence that resource usages can cause



unexpected and even irreversible impacts on the environment.





    Another specific area is that of Applied Research and Technology



Development, in which many of the standard types of research carried on



in the past can be developed more efficiently.





    Finally, Environmental Monitoring and Assessment operations requires



increased research and scientific inputs, to provide more complete and



better integrated feedback for control of undesirable environmental




impacts.






Environmental Systems Interactions





    Both  in terms of priority and frequency of mention in the various



papers,  the overriding research requirement is to develop better knowl-




edge of  the systemic interactions involved in environmental impacts,



research  usage,  and the public interest.   Several existing difficulties



must be overcome.   Caldwell noted that government research programs
                                  245

-------
favor the immediate,  low-risk,  and fragmentary over comprehensive and




long-term studies.  Stanley Cain pointed out that the sciences (except



for ecology) are not  coordinated;  he suggested a version of the classic




land-labor-capital economic model  to yield integrated insights.  Robert



North described several promising  but still inadequate interdisciplinary




approaches.





    A general consensus emerged in audience discussions supporting the




thesis of a  new agenda for environmental research,  including a systematic




approach and a conceptual basis extending beyond the boundaries imposed



by existing  institutional arrangements.   Attendees  agreed that EPA should



avoid the shopping list approach to R&D  and instead develop a hierarchical



structure based on long-term investigations such as alternative futures



studies, even though  the findings  might  go beyond typical mission-oriented




agency boundaries.





    Other comments dealt with the  need for feedback of results:  "We



should pursue the grand design  but at the same time we need to look at



the feedback from what has been done."  One iconoclast suggested "We



should declare a moratorium on  research  until we can look back on what



has been done and decide where  we  should go."





    Other audience participants mentioned limitations that must be ac-



cepted in systems research:   "There are  behavioral  limits to human coop-



eration and  human skills."  "Costs of not doing certain things are not



accounted for."





    Needs for improving implementation of objectives seem equally appar-




ent.   William Ruckelshaus pointed  out that, although the founders of EPA




had intentionally built the organization to tie together the different




aspects of environmental control,  they did not, and  still do not adequately




deal with the interrelationships of environment and society.  Industry



in particular finds extreme difficulty operating under the existing
                                  246

-------
fragmentation of environmental control laws and agencies.  One indus-



trial attendee stated that "environmental laws are impossible because



there seems to be no process or understanding between institutions."



His example illustrated that  meeting  a standard set by a regional con-



trol board did not necessarily mean that the state agency would approve.



Another discussant pointed out conflicting agency regulations for the



water use that have been set by the California Water Quality Control



Board on the one hand and the Coastal Commission on the other hand.





    Other perspectives on the same problem put the responsibility back



on industry.  "industry must take the lead toward establishing a holistic



approach to environmental protection."  "An understanding of the process



is necessary," and "a piecemeal approach will only result in nit-picking



by control agencies."





    According to another discussant, the benefits of a process approach



would foster the public feedback that policymaking needs.  But others



added that public perception of the holistic approach requires apprecia-



tion of the risks taken by institutions moving in this direction.   Simi-



larly, legislative decision-makers who have not been educated to take a



systems view of problems "need to adopt a new orientation."  Typical  of



such barriers are the views of a prominent governor who does not like



the word systematic because "he wants to see a product not a process."





    A final discussant from government thought that the situation was



either "serious but not hopeless or hopeless but not serious."  Pre-



ferring the latter view, he remarked that "we should be relieved by the



fact that a holistic approach is constrained by the political arena"  and



that the big picture is actually easier for an institution with fewer



constraints.  He suggested the university environment because of their




broad investigative charters.
                                   247

-------
    Flexibility is a characteristic of our present environmental control




structure that must be improved.   Cain noted that our social structure



is not geared to technical change, but Maurice Eastin speculated that



Congress will soon develop more flexible environmental control systems.



Ralph d'Arge went even further in foreseeing a fundamental reorganization




of control systems to deal with the emergent new class of environmental



issues that are both uncertain and long term in nature.





    Adaptations to the multivariate and interactive consequences of re-




source impacts will involve more  complex information and understanding.



Among the kinds of secondary and  remote effects that must be addressed



are those of intergenerational tradeoffs (mentioned by d'Arge),  antici-




pated reductions in the intensiveness of agricultural production (men-



tioned by Zierold),  organization  of research efforts within or including



EPA (debated by Woodwell and Caller),  and constraints imposed by state



and local institutions (mentioned in one of the workshops) .   The overall



need arises from increasing evidence,  as McHale pointed  out,  that infor-



mation may be our only really unique resource,  that it is inexhaustible,



and that it can be applied to break the historic correlation between de-



velopment and degradation.






Resource Usage Patterns





    At the second level of the conceptual hierarchy, better knowledge of




resource usage forms a major need.  Participants noted a lack of precise



and well-documented models of resource flows in the economy and environ-




ment,  and Earl Heady described how agricultural models,  in particular,




need improvement to  predict joint production functions,  tradeoffs,  and



multiple outcomes.





    Past operational experience seems sufficient to recommend certain



resource policy changes even without improved research models.




Ruckelshaus,  in recommending more realistic policies, reflected that






                                   248

-------
tough laws and spending have proved to be inadequate criteria for serving



the public interest.  Eastin predicted that EPA programs will shift from



a negative emphasis on waste products to a more positive concern with



by-products, and that to do this the programs will be reorganized around



17 resource processes instead of the present 15 functions.  Another ob-



server felt that too little use is being made of practical know-how de-



veloped by private firms operating in specialized areas and processes.





    Policy conflicts should be resolved by considering the prospective



marginal tradeoffs, but these are not always evident.  For example,



George Woodwell and Sidney Galler disagree over whether oil drilling



will significantly harm fisheries on the Georges Bank.  Galler agreed



with John Zierold that emphasis should be given to preserving agricul-



tural land even at large economic cost, but a member of the audience



protested that no one knows if land is actually better used in agricul-



ture than in urban development.  Even knowledge of the dominant trends



is not always adequate to indicate specific policy; Frank Sebastian



documents how the People's Republic of China seeks food sufficiency not



only by perfecting labor intensive agricultural production, but by opting



when necessary for capital intensive fertilizer imports.  Yet fertilizer



requires large amounts of energy and other resources, and it may be del-



eterious to long-term soil quality and even to the ionosphere.





    Because of the complexities involved in analysis of resource usage,



both Caldwell and Cain recommended more impact research.  Several discus-



sants suggested cost-benefit studies of an advanced nature (but other



discussants discounted the value of conventional cost-benefit and statis-



tical work).   North recommended analysis of the distribution question as



well, so that social alternatives can be defined in advance of expected




technical breakthroughs.
                                   249

-------
    Many specific ideas for research were suggested:

    (1)  Analysis of resource substitutability.

    (2)  Options for energy transitions away from the use of fossil
         fuels, such as burning of forest wood.

    (3)  Environmental experiments.
    (4)  Analyses of ecosystems management objectives .


Incentives for Controlling the Environment

    The second intermediate level  component in the figure deals with the

problem of incentives.  North speculated that energy  and resource problems

are multiplying to the point where they threaten national and world sta-

bility, and that a breakthrough in the form of fusion, solar energy, or

some comparable technology will challenge the values, institutions and
lifestyles of the present  society.   But Zierold  noted that,  in the ab-

sence of breakthroughs in  energy and food,  exporting  countries will gain

more power in the world of the future than the victors of World War II

had in the past.   It is obviously  important to attempt to maintain the

social stability and incentive structure whether such changes occur or

not.  But discussants agreed that  there is now no really unified or co-

herent national environmental policy aimed at future  stability.

    A strategy is needed not only  to derive incentives for the present,

but also for the future.  The incentives must be designed to adapt suc-

cessfully to dynamic instabilities in the resource-environment confron-
tation.  McHale mentioned  satiation  as one stabilizing influence.  He

illustrated its effect with fat ladies,  who in ancient times were status

symbols as conspicuous consumers of  food, but have lost their status in
the current age of food abundance.   Satiation will tend to limit increas-

ing consumption of many of our resources.  However,  satiation will not

have a chance to occur when the balance between  resources and demands
changes too rapidly.
                                  250

-------
    Economic "externalities," in which some of the benefits or costs of



an activity are not imposed directly upon the user but rather on some



external group, may be destabilizing influences.  This problem, men-



tioned by Cooper and others, must be minimized if an incentive system



is to be ultimately successful.  For example, recycling activities are



presently inhibited by the lack of a depletion tax allowance on recycled



materials and the favoritism shown for raw materials in railroad tariffs.





    Ruckelshaus advocated the concept that a control system must be re-



sponsive to new conditions as well as to its original conditions.  In



the case of EPA, he observed that the legal adversary relationship that



is developed around most issues has created a hard "win-lose" atmosphere



in which accommodation and adjustment are difficult.  Eastin also noted



that adjustment of the existing EPA arms-length relationship with indus-



try and the citizenry prevents mutually cooperative efforts in resolving



problems.  Rigidity arises in the context of environmental regulations.



Red tape, conflicting laws, agency conflict, and public apathy were all



mentioned by members of the audience as reasons why large-scale progress



is difficult.  One observer noted that only when special legislative



action is taken (as for instance in the case of the Alaskan Pipeline)



can major, long-term projects be accomplished.





    Lack of planning and coordination has especially deleterious effects



on a company designing and building a plant, for example, where long



lead times are required.  Many of the strongest incentives programs men-



tioned by the speakers — taxes, subsidies, stockpiling programs, ration-



ing, international cooperation (all mentioned by Gordon), and open-space



reserves (mentioned by Zierold)—would be either excessively expensive



or completely infeasible if operated under erratic and rapidly changing



policy guidelines.  Some progress in alleviating this uncertainty was



reported by Frank Sebastian by the setting of recommended 1977 and 1983




water quality effluent control standards.






                                 251

-------
    On the international scene,  it is important to ensure that all coun-




tries accept joint environmental and resource goals.   Robert North sug-



gested that research on international political systems and on compara-




tive national trends can help in these problems,  and  that economic trade



and technology transfer studies  may provide the basis for exchanges that




encompass environmental values as well as national interests.





    Income distribution aspects  may become increasingly significant in




domestic programs.  Problems of  public response,  which were addressed in



several of the workshops,  were largely oriented around how to  derive and



apply social indicators.  In general, incentives  research requires such



techniques as computer simulation,  forecasting,  communications and edu-



cation skills, economic studies  such as the analysis  of revealed behavior



and its relationship to professed values, and (as mentioned by Cain),




even insights obtained from the  humanities.





    In designing controls  for EPA implementation, the first step is to



investigate where the greatest leverage might be  obtained.   Also, one



must examine whether this  leverage is available at a  reasonable cost in



terms of both social acceptance  and technical feasibility.





    Cooper saw two types of control alternatives:  one to more effec-



tively monitor contaminant discharges and actively enforce compliance



through economic incentives, emission standards,  or damage liabilities;



and the other to design an "idiot proof" system utilizing ecologically




sound criteria that can provide  redundant safeguards.  The first of these



alternatives would require considerable development in the areas of mon-




itoring and control, whereas the second would require research in the



area of ecological stability and hardiness.   d'Arge mentioned  the possi-




bility of testing regulatory programs on a limited basis so that experi-




ence can be gained without risking large-scale ecological catastrophes.



Also, experience in control activities at state and local levels can
                                   252

-------
influence policies in wider areas; e.g., Wyoming has adopted some of



Montana's environmental regulations.





    Whatever the techniques involved, several observers note the neces-



sity of developing better methods of information dissemination and com-



munication to the general public on such issues as recycling.  One ex-



pressed it that "the format of information receives too little attention—



particularly for discrimination among different scientific disciplines by



public agencies and the general public."





    Beyond the EPA structure, research must be extended to consider in-



centives of agencies and institutions outside the EPA structure so that



alternative and overlapping approaches may be considered.  One member of



the audience stated that he had flown over an industrial complex at



3 p.m. on a workday and noticed no dirty stack effluents, but at 5:30 p.m.



he observed many smoke emissions.  He presumed this change occurs because



the local air quality control authorities leave work at 4:45 p.m.






Critical Ecological Problems





    At the lowest level of the hierarchy of research priorities in the



figure, programs with the most immediate expected payoff are gathered



together.   One is Critical Ecological Problems—defining research to



discover environmental problems that hold the greatest hazard of severe




or irreversible damage to the environment.





    It is  necessary if not sufficient to review discoveries and theories



of academics and interested environmentalists within the system.   Poten-



tial hazards,  remote as they may seem upon a first hypothesis,  may there-



by be evaluated as quickly as possible.   But the history of science is



ample illustration of the difficulty of establishing review processes



within the structure of an organized establishment.   Ruckelshaus proposed



that we build  in ways for the EPA organization to systematically anticipate
                                   253

-------
 emergent  future problems.  Workshop participants suggested special  stud-




 ies  to  seek out and investigate potentially urgent environmental problems





     Other discussants identified a particular problem in the  field  of




 synthetic plastics.  R&D and manufacturing capacities increasingly  are



 used to develop synthetics as substitute materials for essential and



 critical  materials in short supply.  Since some of the new materials may



 be quite  hazardous environmentally, EPA should sponsor "early warning"



 research  to devise appropriate control mechanisms before these new  syn-



 thetics get into full production.  The group recognized that this is dif-



 ficult because of industry's propensity for secrecy,  especially with




 chemicals.





     In some ways the long-term hazards are more insidious and difficult



 than  the  short-term hazards.  Long-term hazards are harder to identify



 and  eliminate unless a specific effort is made to identify these trends.



 Short-term hazards,  on the other hand, are generally much more evident



 because of the obvious shifts in environmental balances that they create.



 d'Arge suggested that EPA focus on long-term uncertainties as a major




 problem area.   He added that the most difficult aspect of these uncer-




 tainties are those in which interactive effects are operating.  Woodwell



 described a specific example of uncertainty in the observed long-term



 buildup of carbon in the atmosphere,  and its unknown future impact.





     In the worst situation, uncertain hazards may result in irreversible



 changes.  Cooper notes that extinction is such an irreversible change.



 Therefore, he agrees with d'Arge that irreversibility is the ultimate



 environmental  hazard.







Applied Research and Technology Development





    The central base for EPA's research program must  remain its existing




applied research and technology development.   Among these kinds of activ-



 ities, the most notable emphasis was  on recycling.   Zierold stated that




                                   254

-------
 reusability as opposed  to  discard  will  be a  mandatory  trend  in  future



 society.  Among  specific suggestions  for reuse, Woodwell  urged  that



 "closed  systems" be developed  for  local recirculation  and recycling of



 water and sewage.  Such developments  would not only  reduce pollution,



 but would also reduce the  size and complexity of  sewage releasing sys-



 tems at  great savings in resources, energy,  and environment.





    Sebastian documented existing  progress in cleaning up areas:  the



 British  in London, Americans in Lake  Tahoe,  California, and  South Afri-



 cans in  Windhoek, Namibia, have all been able to  demonstrate that ad-



 vanced environmental cleanup efforts  provide positive  savings on a cost-



 benefit  basis alone.  But  additional  recycling research is needed in the



 health and public acceptance aspects  of recycled  municipal water supplies,



 and possibly on health  problems associated with the  use of sludge and



 incinerator ash  residue for commercial  fertilizer.   Primarily,  additional



 information is needed on environmentally safe limits for  the heavy metals



 in these residues.





    Design and employment  of resources  to  extend  life  cycles represents



 an alternative to the recycling approach.  Zierold suggested that labor



 intensive activities, which necessarily involve more careful husbanding



 of resources, will replace current high consumptive, intensive  uses.





    A third approach is to find more  efficiently  the kinds of resources



 that already exist.  Most of the emphasis  in current U.S.  energy policy



 reflects this approach.   Gordon suggested  better  development and appli-



 cation of a number of extraction technologies; he mentions geological



 survey techniques such as aerial,  geochemical, geophysical,  seismographic,



 and electrical methods,  and analytical  techniques such as  the use of



 mathematics and statistics in  reducing  geological data.  He also men-



 tioned the need for improved mining methods  such  as  novel  rock  cutting



 and increased mine automation,   economical  methods of treating low-grade




ores,  and ocean mining and sea water  recovery technologies.




                                  255

-------
    As a fourth approach, Gordon and McHale both mention mineral substi-




tution.  Substitution can involve either the search for new applications




of old materials, or the development of new synthetic materials.





    Several attendees mentioned the need for more effective utilization




of existing research results by EPA.  One mentioned need for a more ade-



quate knowledge of the state of the art in various environmental special-




ties.  To a considerable extent,  such knowledge may be available among a




small group of experts,  so the need might be for more effective communi-



cations with the technical community and the general public.






Environmental Monitoring and Assessment





    Workshop participants agreed  that continuing demands by our society



to maintain current standards of  living in the face of resource shortages



will impose increasing pressures  upon EPA.   As certain of our limited re-



sources become less available (e.g., minerals,  conventional energy sources)



new products will be developed and used not only as substitutes for exist-



ing products,  but also in new niches for which they are especially suited.



These new and substitute products with potential new problems could force



EPA to expend increasing efforts  in monitoring the environment.  Yet, as



Cooper pointed out, effective control even of existing substances will



require considerable development  of present monitoring methods.





    Long-term environmental  effects deserve particular emphasis in the



monitoring problem.  For planning purposes, McHale recommended that as-




sessments be projected to periods as long as 30 to 50 years into the



future.





    Another frequently mentioned  aspect of the monitoring problem is the




need for developing quantitative  relationships between the original




source of disturbance and the resultant environmental change.  For ex-



ample,  Woodwell stated his belief that the total amount of photosynthesis
                                   256

-------
in the world is declining but points out that no detailed quantitative



analysis yet exists to either confirm or disprove his thesis.   Gordon



agreed that EPA needs better economic and planning tools to assess such



long-term impacts, and McHale provided another example in the need to



assess agriculture pollution along with industrial pollution.





    Finally, members of the audience in several of the workshops elabo-



rated on the dominant conference theme that social assessments as well



as physical environmental assessments are needed so that EPA may maintain



its policies in harmony with society.  Social assessment needs point to a



frequently cited requirement for development of better social indicators,



so that environmental and resource programs can be designed to be respon-



sive to a fuller, more far-sighted "quality of life."
                                   257

-------
              APPENDIX




SYMPOSIUM PARTICIPANTS AND ATTENDEES

-------
                               Appendix

                 SYMPOSIUM PARTICIPANTS AND ATTENDEES
SRI contributors were:

    Conference Staff:

         Kendall D. Moll, Senior Operations Analyst
         Joni Rosenbaum, Research Assistant
         Pamela M. Halton, Research Analyst
         Cynthia Kroll, Operations Analyst

    Workshop Rapporteurs:

         Marilyn D. Bagley, Operations Analyst
         Robert E. Fullen, Energy Economist
         Ronald T. Collis, Director, Atmospheric  Sciences
         Eric E. Duckstad, Director, Urban and Regional  Studies
         Gordon W. Newell, Director, Toxicology Department

    Workshop Moderators:

         Mark D. Levine, Operations Analyst
         Egils Milbergs, Policy Analyst
         James D. Bray, Senior Economist
         John W. Ryan,  Senior Operations Analyst
         Buford B. Holt, Ecologist

Speakers, participants, and attendees of the symposium are  listed as
follows:

         Eugene S. Allen, Vice President
         Technical Services
         Cyprus Mines Corporation
         Los Angeles, CA
                                  261

-------
 Wallace  B. Allen,  Director
 Environmental  Quality
 Pacific  Gas  and  Electric  Company
 San Francisco, CA

 *Charles  A. Anderson, President
 Stanford Research  Institute
 Menlo  Park,  CA

 Kiat Ang
 Lawrence Berkeley  Laboratory
 University of  California
 Berkeley, CA

 William  C. Arntz,  Regional Administrator
 Federal  Energy Administration
 San Francisco, CA

 John R.  Bagby, Director
 Institute of Environmental Health
 Colorado State University
 Fort Collins,  CO

 Sandra Baron
 Palo Alto, CA

 Peter  Benenson
 Lawrence Berkeley  Laboratory
 University of  California
 Berkeley, CA

('Ferial S. Bishop,  Ecologist
 Environmental  Protection  Agency - R&D
 Washington,  DC

 Stephen  C. Brown,  Director
 Industrial Market  Development
 Envlrotech
 Belmont, CA

 *Stanley  A. Cain, Professor
 Environmental  Studies
 University of  California
 Santa  Cruz,  CA
                          262

-------
*Lynton K. Caldwell, Professor
 Department of Political Science
 University of Indiana
 Bloomington, IN

 John Charbonneau
 Office of Pesticide Programs
 Environmental Protection Agency
 Washington, DC

*William E. Cooper, Professor
 Department of Zoology
 Michigan State University
 East Lansing, MI

 Charles F. Cooper, Director
 Center for Regional Environmental Studies
 San Diego State University
 San Diego, CA

 Paul Cox, Assistant Director
 California Department of Conservation
 Sacramento, CA

 Linda Craig, Solid Waste Consultant
 League of Women Voters of California
 Menlo Park, CA

*Ralph d'Arge, Professor
 Department of Economics
 University of Wyoming
 Laramie, WY

 David De Bruyn
 Environmental Protection Agency
 Seattle, WA

 Robert Dunkle,  Business Administrator
 Envirotech
 Belmont, CA

*Maurice R.  Eastin, Special Consultant to  the Administrator
 Office of the Administrator
 Environmental Protection Agency
 Washington,  DC
                         263

-------
 Stanley Euston, Chief Planner
 Bay Conservation and Development Agency
 San Francisco, CA

 James M. Erickson, Professor
 Department of Ecology
 California State University at Hayward
 Hayward, CA

 Leon H. Fisher, Dean
 School of Science
 California State University at Hayward
 Hayward, CA

 William B. Freeman, Board Chairman
 Miller Freeman Publications
 Diablo, CA

*Sidney R. Caller, Deputy Assistant Secretary for Environment
  Affairs
 Department of Commerce
 Washington,  DC

 Carl Gerber,  Associate Assistant to Administrator,  R&D
 Environmental Protection Agency
 Washington,  DC

 Michael R. Gill,  Professor
 Department of Political Science
 San Jose State University
 San Jose, CA

 John S. Gilmore,  Senior Research Economist
 University of Denver Research Institute
 University Park
 Denver, CO

*Theodore J. Gordon
 The Futures Group
 Galstonbury,  CT

 W.  Scott Gray, Manager
 Environmental Sciences Group
 Bechtel
 San Francisco, CA
                          264

-------
 Edward Groth III,  Staff Officer
 Environmental Studies Board
 National Academy of Sciences  and Research  Council
 Washington,  DC

 Joel Gustafson,  Chairman
 Ecology Section, Biology Department
 San Francisco,State University
 San Francisco, CA

*Willis W. Harman,  Director
 Center for Study of Social Policy
 Stanford Research Institute
 Menlo Park,  CA

*Earl O. Heady, Director
 The Center for Agricultural & Rural  Development
 Iowa State University
 Ames, Iowa

 James Hibbs
 Envirommental Protection Agency
 Washington,  DC

 Frederic Hoffman,  Research &  Development Representative
 Environmental Protection Agency
 Alameda, CA

 David L. Jameson,  Professor
 Biology Department
 University of Houston
 Houston, Texas

 Robert A. Jones, Chief
 Division of  Environmental Management, Dept. of the Interior
 Bureau of Land and Planning Coordination
 Washington,  DC

 Joseph Jutten, Fire Protection  Engineer
 U.S. Energy  Research and Development Administration
 Oakland, CA
                         265

-------
 Hugh Kaufman,  Assistant to Director
 Office of Solid Waste
 Environmental  Protection Agency
 Washington,  DC

 Ted Kreines, Consultant
 American Institute of Planners
 Tiburon, CA

 Ralph A. Kuiper, Manager
 Fluid Mechanics Laboratory
 Lockheed Research Laboratory
 Palo Alto,  CA

 Lawrence Leopold, Coastal Resource Analyst
 Sea Grant Program
 University of  Southern California
 University Park
 Los Angeles, CA

 William Lockett
 Air Resources  Board,  Evaluation & Planning
 Sacramento,  CA

 Dennis Lachtman, Assistant to  Senior Vice President
 Envirotech
 Menlo Park,  CA

*John McHale, Director
 Center for Integrative Studies
 State University of New York at Binghamton
 Binghamton,  NY

 Dean Merrill
 Lawrence Berkeley Laboratory
 University of  California
 Berkeley, CA

 Frank J. Mesaros, Manager-Environmental  Affairs
 Gulf Mineral Resources Company
 Denver,  CO

 Flora Milans,  Statistician
 Bureau of Land Management
 Dept. of the Interior
 Washington,  DC

                          266

-------
*Robert C. North,  Professor
 Political Science Department
 Stanford, CA

 M. J. Ownings
 Non-Petroleum Fuel Economics
 Gulf Oil Corporation
 Pittsburgh,  PA

 Thomas Priestley
 Association of Bay Area Governments
 Berkeley, CA

 John B. Richardson
 ASARCO, Inc.
 Salt Lake City, Utah

 Michael Rothenberg, Chief of Engineering Evaluation
 Bay Area Air Pollution Control District
 San Francisco, CA

 Edwin B. Royce, Physical Scientist
 Industrial Extractive Processes Division
 Office of Energy, Minerals and Industry
 Environmental Protection Agency
 Washington,  DC

*William D. Ruckelshaus, Attorney
 RuckelShaus, Beveridge and Fairbanks
 Washington,  DC

 Jayant Sathaye, Economist
 Lawrence Berkeley Laboratory
 University of California
 Berkeley, CA

 John D. Saussaman,  Vice President
 Domestic Raw Materials
 Kaiser Steel Corporation
 Oakland, CA

 Crichton Schacht, Environmental Officer
 Department of Housing and Urban Development
 Seattle, WA
                         267

-------
         Richard A. Schmidt, Geologist
         Electric Power Research Institute
         Palo Alto, CA

        *Frank P. Sebastian, Senior Vice President
         Envirotech
         Menlo Park, CA

         Ian R. Straughan, Research Scientist
         Southern California Edison Company
         Rosemead, CA

         Susan Tubbesing, Research Technician
         Institute of Behavioral Science
         University of Colorado
         Boulder, CO

         R. E. Whiting, Chief
         Environmental Quality Branch
         California Department of Water Resources
         Sa cramento, CA

         C. Peairs Wilson
         Office of Western Director at Large
         University of California
         Berkeley, CA

        *George M. Woodwell, Director
         The Ecosystems Center
         Marine Biological Laboratory
         Woods Hole, MA

         Ronald Wyzga
         Environmental Assessment Department
         Electric Power Research Institute
         Palo Alto, CA

        *John Zierold, Legislative Advocate
         Sierra Club
         Sacramento, CA
*
 Asterisks indicate speakers and program participants
                                  268

-------