-------

-------
                         ACKNOWLEDGEMENT
     The authors acknowledge the substantial contribution of ICF,
Inc. and Swep Davis to the appendicies on cost and financing of
indemnification programs.  Preliminary work done by David
Alexander, Mark Grady, Carolyn Link, and Larry Seidel of AMS,
particularly on existing indemnification programs and financing,
proved to De a valuable basis for the report.  The authors
gratefully acknowledge the extensive assistance and direction
provided by the project officer, Ellen Selonick Berick.

-------
                            DISCLAIMER
     This report was prepared under contract to an agency of the
Pnited States Government.  Neither the United States Government
nor any of its employees, contractors, subcontractors, or their
employees makes any warranty, expressed or implied, or assumes
,a.ny legal liability or responsibility for any third party's use
or the results of such use of any information in this report or
represents that its use by such third party would not infringe on
privately owned rights.  Mention of trade names or commercial
products does not constitute endorsement or recommenation for
use.

-------
                          TABLE OF CONTENTS


                                                                Page

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY  	         i

I.    INTRODUCTION   	         1

II.   BACKGROUND ON  INDEMNIFICATION  .  .  .  .	        11

III.  EVALUATION OF  EPA PROGRAMS	        29

IV.   EVALUATION OF  POTENTIAL LOSS CATEGORIES  	       118

V.    CONCLUSIONS	       164

APPENDIX A—
      BACKGROUND ON  INDEMNIFICATION  	       A-l

APPENDIX B—
      REGULATORY AND LEGISLATIVE ALTERNATIVES TO
          INDEMNIFICATION	•.       B-l

APPENDIX C—
      CONSULTATION WITH INDUSTRY	       C-l

APPENDIX D~
      INDEMNIFICATION FINANCING SYSTEMS  	       D-l

APPENDIX E—
      COST AND IMPACTS OF INDEMNIFICATION	       E-l

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Executive Summary



                          EXECUTIVE SUMMARY


                                                                Page


A.    Introduction ..... 	 	    ii

B.    Origin and Meaning of the Study Mandate	    ii

C.    Background on Government Indemnification 	   ill

D.    Criteria for Evaluating the Need for
        Indemnification Within EPA Programs	    iv

E.    Existing EPA Indemnification Programs	     v

      1.  FIFRA § 15	Pesticide Indemnities	     v

      2.  Clean Water Act § 202(a)(3) 	 Encouraging
            Innovative Technology	    vi

      3.  Clean Air Act § 113(b) 	 Unreasonable
            Judicial Enforcement 	   vii

      4.  Clean Water Act § 311(1) 	 Encouraging
            Spills Cleanup  	   vii

F.    Other Possible Indemnification Categories	vill

      1.  The Concept of Loss Categories	viii

      2.  Disclosure of Confidential Business Information. .  .  vili

      3.  Delays in Permit Processing	    ix

      4.  Conflicting and Overlapping Regulatory
            Requirements 	    ix

      5.  Emergencies	    ix

      6.  Unreasonable Administrative Enforcement	     x

      7.  Changes in Agency Policy 	     x

G.    Conclusions	     x
                                 -1-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Executive Summary
                           A.   INTRODUCTION

    This  study  seeks  to  fulfill  the  mandate of  §  25(a)  of the Toxic
Substances  Control  Act  (TSCA)  to determine "whether and under what
conditions,  if  any,  indemnification  should be  accorded  any person as a
result  of any action  taken by  the Administrator"  of EPA.   The study
began with  a detailed investigation  of  existing indemnification pro-
grams (both  within  and outside EPA)  and moved  on  to a consideration of
the potential need  for other indemnification programs under any
current or  projected  activity  at EPA.   Both phases involved extensive
discussions  with  EPA  staff and informal consultation with knowledge-
able people  in  the  industries  regulated by EPA.  We could not conclude
that there  is a total lack of  situations justifying indemnification,
nor could we conclude that there are conditions which always Justify
payment.  In the  context  of the  strong  bias against compensation of
regulated parties for the cost of government regulations, there was
insufficient evidence of  a need  for  new indemnification programs at
this time.

             B.   ORIGIN AND MEANING  OF  THE STUDY  MANDATE

    The § 2S(a) study mandate  has roots in the  1972 amendments to the
Federal Insecticide,  Fungicide,  and  Rodenticide Act (FIFRA).  Those
amendments  require  EPA to indemnify  pesticide  owners suffering losses
when EPA  suspends and then cancels a pesticide  registration without
giving  the  owners an  opportunity to  sell or use their pesticide
stocks.   The Senate had originally opposed this FIFRA provision, and
later attempted to  repeal it and to  prevent its inclusion in TSCA.
Instead of either repealing the  FIFRA provision or extending it to
TSCA, Congress  enacted the mandate for  an EPA  study of  indemnifi-
cation.

    The term "indemnification" refers to a particular kind of compen-
sation or reimbursement.   One  of the most well  known examples is an
insurance contract, in which the insurer agrees to indemnify the
insured against loss  arising from a  specific event.  An equitable
right of  indemnity may arise where a person has discharged a duty
owed by him, which  should have been  discharged  by another.

    Indemnification,  as contemplated by the study mandate, has a very
limited meaning,  distinct from many  other kinds of payment and compen-
sation that  the government makes to  private parties. For example,
awards made  by a  court of law, payments under contracts for services
or materials provided to  the government,  entitlement payments and sub-
sidies are all different  from  indemnification under this  study.

    Indemnification cannot be  justified for all losses  due to regula-
tory action  by  the  government.   But  some losses do merit  compensation
under our laws, (e.g., the taking of land to build a military base).
At the other end  of the spectrum,  most  of the routine regulation by
                                -ii-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Executive Summary
 the  government  imposes  costs  that  are  accepted as  normal costs of
 doing  business  and  are  not  considered  to  be  compensable.  Clearly,  the
 government  cannot protect the public health  and welfare without
 causing  some  burdens; and it  could  never  afford to pay for all of
 them.  The  mandate  of the study  is  to  explore  the  gray arias beyond
 those  losses  already covered  by  compensation to determine whether
 there  are additional circumstances  which  might merit  indemnification.

            C.  BACKGROUND  ON GOVERNMENT  INDEMNIFICATION

    American  law has generally not  allowed compensation for losses
 resulting from  regulation.  Even those laws  abrogating immunity have
 narrowly defined the areas  in which the government can be sued.
 Compensation  under  the  Fifth  Amendment has been limited to circumstan-
 ces when full title to  property  is  actually  taken, all the normal
 benefits of owning  the  property  are destroyed,  or  an  important prop-
 erty right  is transferred to  another private person.   Exceptions to
 the Federal Tort Claims Act's waiver of sovereign  immunity have pre-
 vented tort suits for the results of most policy decisions, by
 excluding activities involving discretionary functions,  misrepresenta-
 tions, and many intentional torts.

    Congress has only infrequently  provided  indemnification,  and a
 decision to grant indemnification generally  has not been regarded as a
 precedent for its use in other circumstances.

    Instances of congressionally-granted  indemnification can be cate-
 gorized according to three  indemnification goals:

    •   compensating some inequity;

    •   deterring an agency from undesirable action;  and

    •   encouraging or permitting desired private  activity or other-
        wise facilitating a public  goal.

    Most equitable indemnification  situations  have been congressio-
nally handled on a case-by-case  basis  through  use  of  the private-bill
mechanism.  However, when there  are a  sufficient number of indem-
niflable incidents of a predictable and regular type,  Congress may
establish some type of indemnification  process,  rather than deal with
each situation individually.   On the other hand, most  prospective
indemnification programs established by public  laws have been intended
as disincentives to government action  or'as  incentives to private-
party action.  Some of the instances for which  Indemnification has
been granted include:

    •   Indemnification for the  consequences of  product  bans
        (pesticides under § 15 of FIFRA);                    :"
                                 -iii-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Executive Summary
     •   Agricultural indemnities to farmers (beekeepers,  contaminated
         milk,  diseased livestock,  and the contaminated  cranberry inci-
         dent  of 1959);

     •   Reimbursement for oil and  hazardous substance spill removal
         costs  (§ 311(1)  of the Clean Water Act;  the Outer Continental
         Shelf  Lands Act  of 1978; and the Comprehensive  Environmental
         Response,  Compensation and Liability Act of 1980);

     •   Indemnification  to encourage use of innovative  pollution
         control equipment (§  202(a)(3)  of the Clean Water Act
         authorizing EPA  funding of replacement or modification of
         failed innovative wastewater treatment facilities);

     •   Arts and Artifacts Indemnity Act (losses incurred by museums
         exhibiting internationally loaned art);

     •   Government contractors'  indemnification  (defense  contractors
         are promised indemnity for unusually hazardous  activities,
         NASA reauthorization  of 1981 covering indemnities for  certain
         catastrophic losses);

     •   Swine  flu  vaccine program  (acceptance of liability  exposure
         rather than reimbursement  of losses);

     •   Indemnification  for government  misrepresentation  (private
         bills  covering the Mitzokami spinach and Marlin toys cases);
         and

     •   Attorneys'  fees and  court costs for certain unreasonable
         agency actions  (§ 113(b)  of the Clean Air Act  Amendments of
         1977  and  the Equal Access to Justice Act of 1980).

     Congress is currently considering an indemnification  mechanism  for
certain  firms  who  suffered losses  when  the  chemical flame-retardant
Tris  was prohibited  in children's  sleepwear.   Also,  the Trial
Commissioner of the  Court of  Claims should  soon  file an opinion in  the
case  of  California growers and  canners  seeking indemnification for
losses suffered when cyclamates  were banned in 1969.

      D.  CRITERIA FOR EVALUATING  THE NEED  FOR INDEMNIFICATION
          WITHIN EPA PROGRAMS

    No detailed formula  was developed which could automatically deter-
mine  whether indemnification might be necessary  in any  particular set
of circumstances.  Instead, a  review of  previous incidents and
existing indemnification programs  revealed  relevant factors  for ana-
lyzing EPA indemnification programs and  assessing whether their use
should be expanded or  whether  entirely  new  indemnification programs
are needed or  any  specific situations require  indemnities.   These fac-
tors  include:
                                   -iv-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Executive  Summary
     •    The  nature of  the  reasons  supporting  indemnification
         (compensation  on equitable grounds; disincentive  to government
         action; to encourage or  facilitate private  sector or  regulated
         party activity);

     •    Whether an anticipatory  indemnification  program (as opposed  to
         ad_ hoc decisions)  Is necessary;

     •    Availability of preferable alternatives  to  indemnification;

     •    Whether Congress has considered the issue of  compensation or
         other remedies in  the situation at hand  and expressed a  posi-
         tion which is  determinative of the question;

     •    The  extent to  which indemnification supports  or conflicts with
         other program  objectives;

     •    Cost predictability and  the amount of indemnity payout and
         administration cost compared with the benefit derived;

     •    Whether the particular indemnification can  be effectively
         financed and administered in a manner which does  not  unaccep-
         tably interfere with the administration  of  other  programs.

              E.  EXISTING EPA INDEMNIFICATION PROGRAMS

     The  study is grounded  in an  examination of the  indemnification
programs already in existence at EPA, and consideration of whether
they should be expanded to other situations.  This  has provided  a more
concrete basis for evaluation than a theoretical construction would.

1.   FIFRA  § 15 	 Pesticide Indemnities

     The  §  15 provision appears to have been the  result of legislative
compromise and a unique, multifaceted combination of  factors.  It does
not  appear to be typical of other Indemnification programs in the
government.  Therefore, it is difficult to generalize from the
experience under § 15.

     The  essential elements of §  15 are:  that the government  suspend
and  then cancel the registration of a pesticide without allowing
owners to  sell or use  their inventories.  There have  been very few
emergency  suspensions  since 1972, and only three have met the criteria
for  indemnification.  Only one of those was a commercial  pesticide.

     EPA  has never developed regulations or guidance documents  to
implement  § 15.  Instead, claims-processing procedures were developed
in 1979 during the Silvex case,  through an agreement  negotiated  pri-
marily between EPA and Chevron Chemical Company.  Under the agreements
signed by  18 registrants, indemnity claims were funneled  through each
                                    -v-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Executive  Summary
flc  funding  reserve  to  assure  the  availability  of money  when  It  is
needed.   In  addition, payment  of indemnification is  entirely
discretionary.

     In the context of demonstration  projects, a substitute  for govern-
ment indemnification exists  In the form of  private Insurance  which
could be  purchased out  of demonstration-project funds  In order to pro-
tect against  the  risk of failure or  of damage to the source's
equipment.   In addition, contingent  Indemnification  clauses have been
provided  to EPA clean-up contractors under  Superfund.  Nevertheless,
if the use of innovative technology  is to be strongly  encouraged, and
if Congress  is willing  to write an indemnification guarantee, then
such a provision  might  provide a substantial savings compared to the
use  of commercial insurance.   c

3.  Clean Air Act §  113(b) 	 Unreasonable Judicial Enforcement

    Section  113(b) of the Clean Air Act provides that  a  federal  court
may award costs of litigation  (including reasonable  attorney  and
expert witness fees) to a party against whom erroneous or harassing
enforcement action Is brought  by EPA.  The  legislative history of this
provision Indicates  that It  was intended to encourage  persons who
would not otherwise  do  so for  economic reasons  to raise  a legitimate
defense to such actions, and to serve as a deterrent against  unreason-
able enforcement  litigation.

    Congressional concern over the potential for harassing  or other-
wise "unreasonable"  litigation under the Clean  Air Act does not  appear
to have been borne out  in fact.  Only one case  has ever  resulted in a
§ 113(b)  award, and  there are  no indications that EPA's  judicial
enforcement efforts  are perceived  to be arbitrary or harassing.  EPA
enforcement policies and concurrence procedures also seriously
restrict  the potential  for such action in the future.  For  these same
reasons,  indemnities for judicial actions in other EPA enforcement
programs  are also not necessary.

4.  Clean Water Act  § 311(1) 	 Encouraging Spills  Cleanup

    Section 311(1) of the Clean Water Act encourages nonliable
dischargers to assist in oil spill cleanup efforts by  promising  to
indemnify such dischargers for reasonable cleanup costs.  Thus,  a
cleanup incentive is provided  to the party most knowledgeable of the
content and amount of a spill,  and the party most likely to be first
aware that it has occurred.

    Hazardous substance spills are also covered under  §  311(1),  but
cleanup is largely managed under the terms of the recently  enacted
Comprehensive Environmental Response, Compensation and Liability Act
(CERCLA).  This new  statute  provides up to $1.6 billion  over  a five-
year period to respond  to harmful releases of pollutants  in all  of the
                              -vii-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Executive Summary
 registrant.   While  the  administrative  processing of claims was still
 very  difficult  for  EPA,  this  arrangement  made processing feasible
 despite  the  large number of  Silvex  indemnity claims received from
 retailers  and distributors.   After  final  review of each claims
 package, EPA informed  the registrant of  the claims amount which the
 Agency considered "appropriate."  However,  the Agency also stated that
 it  had no  money with which to pay the  claims.  Subsequently, some of
 the registrants successfully  obtained  indemnity payments from the
 Court of Claims Judgment Fund.  The Department of Justice recently
 settled  seven Silvex cases for  a  total of $18.7 million.

    A variety of arguments fueled the  congressional debate over § 15.
 In  the ten years since  the provision's enactment, some of these argu-
 ments have proved to be  insubstantial, while others have taken on new
 weight.  Although existing evidence does  not warrant repeal of the
 § 15  indemnity  program,  there are significant operational problems,
 especially the  program's lack of  a  specific funding mechanism.  There
 are also administrative  problems  that  result from the infrequent need
 to  handle  a  very large  volume of  claims.

    Extension of an indemnity program  to  the toxics area for loss of
 inventory  like  that in  FIFRA  §  15 does not  appear to be necessary.  In
 the toxics area there is no evidence of the kind of losses envisioned
 by  the drafters of  § 15,  due  to the differences between the statutes
 and their  subject matter.  TSCA contains  many methods for preventing,
 limiting and  sharing the costs  of regulation.  Experience in imple-
 menting TSCA  is of  course  limited,  but so far there are no patterns of
 inequities that would justify establishment of an indemnification
 program.   Decisions on whether  isolated inequities justify an indem-
 nification payment  should  be  made based on  the facts of the case, and
 cannot be  forecast.

 2.  Clean Water Act § 202(a)(3) 	 Encouraging Innovative
    Technology

    The indemnification  provision of § 202(a)(3) of the Clean Water
Act was designed, in part, as an  Incentive  to encourage the use of
 innovative and  alternative wastewater  treatment technology by local
 governments.  The statute  gives EPA discretion to fund 100% of the
costs of modifying  or replacing a facility  that fails to meet perfor-
mance specifications and has  significantly  increased operating or
maintenance expenses.  Although the provision has only very limited
application to  provide replacement  or  modification funds for any
failed treatment facilities,  its  very  existence has encouraged gran-
tees  to use innovative or  alternative  technology.  Funding of replace-
ment  or modification costs has  not  yet occurred, because eligible
facilities have  only recently become operational.

    The practical effectiveness of  this provision as an incentive for
the use of innovative technology  is diminished by the lack of a speci-
                                  -vi-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Executive Summary
 pollution  media.   While  CERCLA has  no provision  identical to § 311(1),
 a  similar  incentive  is  possible under §  lll(a),  which  provides for the
 payment  of certain claims,  including necessary response  costs incurred
 by any person  as  a result  of  carrying out  the national contingency
 plan.  However,  these expenses must be approved  in  advance by EPA,
 according  to current EPA policy.  This is  to ensure cost control,  and
 effective  management of  cleanup operations.

    The  experience under §  311(1) demonstrates that it has been suc-
 cessful  in accomplishing congressional purposes,  although on only  a
 limited  basis.  It cannot  be  determined  yet whether CERCLA ultimately
 will provide an effective  alternative to § 311(i);  and any con-
 sideration of  expanding  §  311(1) should  await further  experience in
 implenting CERCLA.                          c

            F.  OTHER POSSIBLE INDEMNIFICATION CATEGORIES

 1.  The  Concept of Loss  Categories

    In addition to considering possible  extensions  or  transplants  of
 existing EPA indemnification  programs to other EPA  program areas,
 otter possible circumstances  under  which indemnification might be
         d  were evaluated.   In this  regard, categories  more likely  to
         indemnifiable situations were identified  and specific indemni-
 fiable event losses were sought in  order to sharpen the  analysis and
 assess the seriousness of  the problems.  In this  process,  each
 environmental  statute and  its major regulations were reviewed, discus-
 sions were held with past  and current EPA staff,  and industry sources
 were consulted for identification of potentially  indemnifiable situa-
 tions.   Five loss  categories  were selected for more detailed evalua-
 tion to  determine  the need  for indemnification.

 2.  Disclosure of  Confidential Business  Information

    Industry has been quite concerned with the problem of losses
 resulting  from government disclosure of  confidential business informa-
 tion (CBI J required to be submitted to government agencies.   Industry
 has therefore attempted  to  persuade Congress and  the federal judiciary
 to define  CBI better and to narrow  the scope of authorized CBI disclo-
 sure or  use.  However, government indemnification has  not been sought
 for losses  due either to authorized or to unauthorized government
 disclosure  of CBI.

    An EPA  Indemnification  program  does  not seem warranted to remedy
 such losses.  Both negligent  and intentional unauthorized disclosures
are already arguably subject  to a suit for money damages under the
Federal Tort Claims Act.  Furthermore, EPA has detailed  security pro-
         in  the pesticides and toxics  areas designed  to safeguard CBI
         uthorized  disclosure.   There  are also substantial criminal
pwities  for intentional unauthorized disclosure.   No claims have
                                   -viii-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Executive Summary
 been  filed  against  EPA seeking compensation for  these  types  of  losses,
 and  there have  been no prosecutions  or  disciplinary  actions  for inten-
 tional  and  unauthorized disclosure.   With regard to  authorized
 disclosures,  congressional  consideration is being given  to amendments
 to the  CBI  portion  of  the Freedom of Information Act,  as well as to
 amendments  to FIFRA which relate  to  CBI disclosure.

 3.  Delays  in Permit Processing

    An  indemnification program also  does not seem warranted  to  deal
 with  the alleged  problem of losses due  to delays in  government  permit
 processing.   Both industry  and EPA representatives concerned with the
 problem of  permit delays have  focused on remedial solutions  other than
 indemnification.  Furthermore, several  studies have  indicated that the
 causes  of delays  in construction  of  new power plants and other
 industrial  facilities  are not  limited to regulatory  problems.
 Instead, many delays result from  other  problems  such as  financing,
 labor and equipment availability,  and management difficulties.

 A.  Conflicting and Overlapping Regulatory Requirements

    The problem of  conflicting and overlapping regulatory requirements
 does not appear to  be  sufficiently significant to warrant an indemni-
 fication program.   No  conflicting  regulatory interactions warranting
 indemnification appeared in a  review of EPA programs.  At worst, the
 instances found represent compliance costs made  necessary by reason of
 other regulatory  standards.  This  is not normally regarded as a basis
 for compensation.

 5.  Emergencies

    Although  emergency action  seems  theoretically to provide increased
 chances for creating an indemnifiable loss,  our  search did not  reveal
 any such Indemnifiable circumstances.   The agency has  rarely used its
 emergency authority to curtail private  operations.   One  situation
 involved an air pollution episode  in Birmingham,  Alabama in  1971 in
which a temporary restraining  order,  obtained in  the  middle of the
night under § 303 of the Clean Air Act  was in effect for 32  hours.
The other incident  involved  the temporary halting of operations of an
FMC plant in  West Virginia  that was  leaking carbon tetrachloride into
 the Kanawa River.   Where emergency authority is  used,  a  judge deter-
mines that the imminent threat to  public health  requires the unusual
action.  A new and  comprehensive  law (CERCLA) governs  response  to
emergencies, generated  by release of  hazardous substances.  It appears
 to limit the  possibilities  for unwarranted burdens on  private parties.
Until more experience  indicates a  need  for assistance  beyond Superfund
and the contingent  Indemnity provision  for clean-up  contractors, no
new indemnification in this  area program should  be recommended.
                                   -ix-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Executive Summary
 6.   Unreasonable Administrative Enforcement

     An expanded indemnity program to compensate persons subject to
 unreasonable administrative enforcement is probably not warranted.
 This is primarily because there is no evidence that clearly unreason-
 able enforcement exists on more than a very infrequent basis, and
 because EPA's current enforcement policies and concurrence procedures
 make such occurrences less likely than ever before.  In addition, it
 would seem preferable to accomplish Agency restraint through tradi-
 tional avenues of judicial review, rather than indirectly by the
 threat of indemnification.  The former route would encourage loss
 anticipation and avoidance, while the latter route, if designed
 effectively, could result in excessive restraint and thus interfere
 with the Agency's enforcement mission.

 7.   Changes in Agency Policy

     No indemnification program appears to be warranted to deal with
 the  problems associated with changes in Agency policy.  Such changes
 are  incidental to the activities and responsibilities of almost every
 federal agency.   For  the most part,  the parties subject to regulatory
 programs at EPA have  long been aware of the potential losses they may
 incur because of changes in the programs.   The regulatory process
 allows for adequate forewarning of changes and such changes are a nor-
 mal  commercial risk of doing business.

                            G.   CONCLUSIONS

     No determinative  indemnity formula was devised.  Our study of sta-
 tutory and  other legal indemnification precedents  and theories and our
 consideration of the  numerous factors that might be applied,
 demonstrated  that  indemnity factors  vary in applicability and impor-
 tance  depending  on individual circumstances,  and that these cir-
 cumstances  will  almost always be different in some important aspect.
 Congress  must make such exceptional  decisions,  as  it has in the past,
 based  on  legislative  criteria that are best defined at the time the
 issue  arises  and the  unique facts of the situation are known.

    No  new  indemnification programs  are warranted  at this time.  This
 conclusion  is  based on findings that (a)  no justification currently
 exists  for  expanding  existing  EPA indemnification  programs into new
 areas  of  EPA  jurisdiction,  (b)  an analysis of likely loss areas
demonstrates  that  there  is  no  justification for concluding that there
will actually  be losses  that  should  be indemnified under any of the
 criteria  used  by Congress  in  the  past,  and (c)  there is  little current
 interest  on  the  part  of  Industry  in  the  availability of  such a remedy
 for actions  taken  by  EPA.

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Executive  Summary
    Other important conclusions concerning  indemnification  based upon
equitable grounds include:

    •   Whether indemnification is warranted  for an  inequity  raises
        complex issues that are best considered in the  context of  the
        specific case and not resolved in advance by legislating a
        prospective indemnification program*

    •   Procedural protections may reduce the need for  indemni-
        fication.

    •   Indemnification for inequities has  not resulted  in  domino-like
        extensions of Indemnification to to other situations.

    •   Some alleged inequities are not unique to EPA,  and  solutions,
        if warranted, may need to be government-wide in  scope.

    •   The private bill process can continue to provide relief of
        last resort for Inequities arising  from EPA  action*

    Other important conclusions regarding indemnification to  provide
incentives or disincentives are:

    •   Indemnification has worked to provide incentives to parties
        outside the government

    •   Indemnification for the purpose of  restraining  certain unde-
        sirable agency action is not clearly justified  based  on
        experience under existing EPA programs.  Moreover,  the poten-
        tial for adverse impact warrants very careful consideration
        before legislating an indemnification program for this
        purpose.
                                  -xi-

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Section I
                          I.  INTRODUCTION
      Study Approach.
      1.  Overview. .	   2
      2.  Phase I	   2
      3.  Phase II	   3
      4.  Phase III	   4
      5.  Report	   5

B.    Major Issues.	   7

      I.  "Any Person"	   7
      2.  "Indemnification" 	   7
      3.  The Question of an Indemnification Formula	   7
      4.  "Federal Laws Administered by the Administrator". . .   8
      5.  Other Environmental Losses. ... 	   8

C.    Other Information . *	10
                                 -1-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Section  I
                          A.   STUDY APPROACH

1.  Overvlev

    In  1976,  Congress  passed  §  25(a) of  Che Toxic Substances  Control
Act (TSCA)  requiring,  in  part,  that the  EPA Administrator  conduct  a
study of  the  need  for  indemnification under EPA-admlnistered  statutes.
This study  would be  "for  the  purpose of  determining whether and  under
what conditions, if  any,  indemnification should be accorded any  person
as a result of  any action taken by the Administrator under [all
Federal laws  administered by  EPA]."  This report responds  to  the
§ 25(a) mandate by clarifying the government indemnification  concept
and by evaluating  its  suitability as a remedy for losses that have
been or might be sustained under specific EPA programs.

    During  this study,  Interviews were conducted with persons repre-
senting the agency,  industry, Congress,  and envlromental groups.
Indemnification precedents (both in and  outside EPA programs) were
studied in  detail, and  consideration has been given to the potential
need for  indemnification  for  current and projected EPA activities.

    The study was  performed in  three separate (but partially  overlap-
ping) phases.   Phase I  involved an analysis of the indemnification
concept and a study  of  principal indemnification precedents.  Phase II
involved  a  detailed  analysis  of existing EPA indemnification  programs.
Finally,  Phase  III Involved an  analysis  of all EPA programs to deter-
mine whether an indemnification remedy might be warranted  where  it
does not  already exist.   For  the most part, these three phases were
conducted independently,  and  have been treated separately  in  the
report.

2.  Phase I
    During Phase I, a thorough study of government  indemnification was
conducted.  This study included a review of non-EPA public and  private
bills in which indemnification was granted, and cases referred  (by a
special procedure) to the Court of Claims for recommendation.   To
help define the vague language of the study mandate it also  included
research into the legislative debates behind § 25(a) of TSCA and  § 15
of the Federal Insecticide, Fungicide and Rodenticide Act (FIFRA) (a
major indemnification provision under EPA authority which was con-
sidered as a possible model for § 25(a) indemnification).  Finally, it
included a thorough review of previous and current  government policies
pertaining to the compensation of persons adversely affected by
government activity.  This entailed an analysis of  the Constitution's
Fifth Amendment, legislative exceptions to the principle of  sovereign
immunity (especially the Federal Torts Claims Act), and judicially
created compensation precedents.  It also entailed  a review  of  all
potentially relevant legislative issues currently before Congress,
including such general topics as regulatory reform, regulatory  relief

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Section I
and  federal budget control,  as well as  specific topics,  such  as
currently  proposed bills  to  provide relief  to asbestos-exposed workers
and  to  provide black  lung  benefits.

    From this review, factors were identified which Congress  appears
to have applied when  determining the appropriateness of  indemnifica-
tion.  These are the  compelling characteristics that influence a  deci-
sion to deviate from  the normal policy  of not compensating  for the
cost of complying with regulations.  In broad categories  they include:

    •   Fairness, equity,  due process (e.g., detrimental  reliance,
        government error);

    •   The availability of  alternative loss avoidance or relief
        mechanisms;

    •   The potential impact (Interference or support) on agency
        missions;

    •   Consistency with other congressional policies (e.g.,  the
        policy against compensating regulated parties, the  policy of
        subsidizing certain  constituencies); and

    •   Feasibility (e.g., costs, financing, administration).

    As a part of this review, Instances of congresslonally  supported
indemnification were categorized according to their major goals.
These categories include:

    •   Indemnification to remedy some  inequity (e.g., losses due to a
        government mistake that are not otherwise compensable under
        federal law).

    •   Indemnification to deter an agency from undesirable action.

    •   Indemnification to promote some desirable activity by a party
        other than the federal government (e.g., destruction  of
        diseased livestock to prevent spread of the disease).

    These efforts provided an analytical framework for evaluating EPA
programs In Phases II and III.  During  the latter phases, indemnifica-
tion factors and goals were continually reevalutated and  refined  as
their use in actual application became more clearly understood.

3.  Phase II

    During Phase II,  all EPA-implemented statutes were reviewed to
identify and categorize existing indemnification programs.  Four  EPA
indemnity programs were identified:   (1) § 15 of FIFRA (compensation
for losses due to emergency suspensions and cancellations of  pesti-
                                 -3-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section I
 cide registrations); (2) § 202(a)(3) of  the Clean Water Act (CWA)
 (government grants to cover the costs of replacing innovative waste
 treatment facilities that do not work);  (3) §  311(i) of CWA
 (reimbursement of cleanup costs for certain oil and chemical spills);
 and (4) § 113(b) of Clean Air Act (CAA)  (reimbursement of attorneys'
 fees for unreasonable enforcement).

     In each case, the legislative goals and the major issues of
 legislative debate were researched and examined.  Then, interviews and
 research explored (a) how the program has worked, (b) whether
 congressional goals were achieved, (c) whether the congressional
 debate was accurate in its consideration of advantages and
 disadvantages, (d) whether new advantages and disadvantages have been
 suggested by actual experience, and (e) whether modification (or a
 reevaluation of the need for) the program is warranted.  This research
 included discussions with staff from EPA, the Department of Justice,
 and other governmental agencies involved In implementing indemnifica-
 tion programs; discussions with industry officials affected by the
 programs; and a review of appropriate regulations, guidelines,
 memoranda, and indemnification decisions.

 4.  Phase III

     Based on the research conducted in Phases I and II, a review of
 all EPA programs was conducted to determine whether there have been or
 might be instances in which Indemnification is appropriate.  This was
 approached from three angles.  First, research was conducted to deter-
 mine whether existing indemnification programs should be expanded into
 other statutory areas.  Essential justifications for each of the four
 existing EPA indemnification provisions were defined and then compared
 to other EPA programs to determine whether similar circumstances might
 exist.

     The second approach was to look for patterns of loss due to pre-
 sent or threatened EPA action under any EPA statute.  The logical
 places  to find mention of losses were in Industry complaints about
 environmental regulation, administrative enforcement cases, rulemaking
'comments and petitions, and actions for judicial review, and through
 discussions  with EPA, industry and environmental organization
 representatives.   This research resulted In a list of six loss cate-
 gories  meriting close examination:

     (1)  disclosure of confidential business information,

     (2)  delays in EPA action (e.g.,  permit or variance review),

     (3)  conflicting requirements,

     (4)  emergency actions,
                                  -4-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section I
     (5)   unreasonable  administrative  enforcement,  and

     (6)   changes  in policy.

     Major EPA  programs were  screened  to identify possible contexts
where  losses would  be  most apt  to  occur.   Then,  each category was ana-
lyzed  for the  programs involved by applying the  factors identified
during Phases  I and II,  and  conclusions were reached regarding the
probable  need  for indemnification.

     A  third task  involved consultation  with industry representatives
and  other persons.   One  critical indication*of a need  for indemnifica-
tion in specific  instances is  that affected persons  express  a need for
compensation.  This, in  fact, has  been  the traditional manner in which
any  kind  of special subsidization  or  compensatory  relief has been
granted in the past.

     No comprehensive survey  was conducted.   However, major trade
associations were consulted  regarding their knowledge  of incidents for
which  indemnification  might  be  considered  appropriate.   These persons
were also asked their  opinion on the  general desirability of new indem-
nification programs.   Trade  association representatives often referred
us to  specific industry  contacts.   In addition,  industry representa-
tives  were called to discuss specific issues Involving their industry
as they arose.  The list of  organizations  contacted  during this  study
is provided as Appendix  C to this  report.

5.   Report

     The results of  all three phases of  study are reported here.   A
background section  introduces the  reader to the  concept of government
indemnification,  explaining  its historical  basis and tracing its
development.   Factors  affecting any indemnification  decision are
briefly described,  and an analytical  method for  evaluating EPA
programs  is presented.

    The evaluation  of  EPA programs  follows  and is  presented  in two
separate  sections.  First we examine  existing EPA  indemnification
programs  and the  need  for extending these  programs to  closely anala-
gous circumstances.  Second, other  loss categories are  evaluated for
all EPA programs.

    At the end of the  report, conclusions  are presented,  along with a
summary of findings supporting  the conclusions and an  explanation of
the  reasoning  involved.

    Appendix A contains  detailed background information which supple-
ments  Section II.  Appendix  B discusses various  remedial or  loss
avoidance  mechanisms which may  be alternatives to  indemnification.  As
noted,  Appendix C presents a list of  the organizations  contacted
                                 -5-

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Section I
during this study.  Appendix D discusses means of financing indemnifi-
cation programs.  Appendix E presents a methodology for estimating the
cost, including two examples that illustrate the problems.
                                 -6-

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                            Section  I
                          B.  MAJOR ISSUES

    In addressing the requirements of § 25(a), numerous  issues  of
interpretation were raised.  The major issues are described  below.
                                I
1.  "Any Person"

    According to § 25(a), the goal of the study would  be to  determine
whether indemnification should  be accorded  "any person as  a  result  of
any action taken by the Administrator."  An issue for  interpretation
was whether "any person" should include all persons  potentially
affected by EPA actions, including not only the directly injured
party, but also persons dependent on that party to some  degree  (e.g.,
employees, purchasers), or persons incurring injury  indirectly  because
of the action's effect on the directly injured party (e.g.,  consumers,
local community).

    This question was resolved  by limiting  the study to  directly
injured parties.  For example,  a ban on the sale and use of  pesticides
would directly affect both manufacturers and growers,  but  only
indirectly affect the farm product purchasers.  The  latter type of
injury has not been covered In  this study.  This restriction in scope
was necessary to allow for achievement of reasonable project goals
within an acceptable budget and timeframe.  Moreover,  the  need  to
reimburse indirect loses may be evaluated,  if necessary,  in  the same
analytical framework applicable to directly injured  parties.

2.  "Indemnification"
    Another major issue involved the definition  of  "indemnification."
Should the study be restricted to circumstances  involving  reimburse-
ment of a person for claims paid by that person  (the  traditional
definition), or should it Include, in addition,  other costs  incurred
as a result of the agency action?  A review of the  legislative  history
of § 25(a) indicated congressional interest in the  need  to reimburse
any costs associated with EPA action, and  the study has  been struc-
tured to consider all circumstances involving any reimbursable  costs.

3.  The Question of an Indemnification Formula

    One way to fulfill the mandate of § 25(a) would be  to  define
criteria, assign weights to them and fashion them into  a formula  that
could be applied to any loss situation to  determine whether  or  not
indemnification was warranted.  An attempt was made during this study
to design such an indemnification formula.  In the  end,  however,  no
predictive formula could be stated.  From  this attempt  we  concluded
that certain criteria should always be considered,  but  the issue  of
whether indemnification Is warranted is ultimately  a  question of
policy and circumstances.
                                  -7-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Section  I
    Much  of  the  report  focuses on whether  a  prospective  indem-
nification program  is warranted.  The  criteria  governing  decisions  to
establish indemnification programs  are more  objective  and easier  to
generalize than  those applying to individual payments.  However,  this
does not  reflect  a  conclusion that  there are no  Individual circumstan-
ces in which indemnification is appropriate.  Instead, this report
attempts  to  provide some guidance on how such decisions should  be
made.

4.  "Federal Laws Administered by the Administrator"

    Although the  study  requirement  pertains  to  all  federal laws imple-
mented by EPA, only major environmental statutes were  considered, and
among these, only those provisions  pertaining directly to environmen-
tal protection were evaluated.  Thus, among  the  laws and  provisions
excluded  from consideration in this study  are those concerning  civil
rights, contracts,  civil service, employment, and environmental con-
sultation to other  agencies.

5.  Other Environmental Losses

    In the course of research for this project,  several examples  of
environmentally related losses were brought  to our attention.   For  a
variety of reasons,  they do not fall into  the scope of the study  man-
date which Is to  consider losses caused by actions of  the
Administrator under any of the laws administered by EPA.   As the
reader of this study is likely to be familiar with at  least some  these
examples, we set  forth  the reasons  that they  do  not appear in this
study:

    •   Health effects of old hazardous waste sites.  Injuries  from
        hazardous waste sites are directly caused by those who  build
        and  maintain them and only  indirectly by the government.  If
        the  Injury  was caused before EPA had  been given regulatory
        authority,  there would be no basis for a claim against  the
        Agency.   This would not fall into  the category of formal  deci-
        sions not to take action which have  been considered Agency
        actions for  the purposes of this study.

    •   Conflicts with state common law.  A  state court ordered the
        owner of  a  hazardous waste disposal  site to close it and
        dispose of  the waste elsewhere.  Even though the  disposal site
        had  been  in  compliance with EPA regulations, it was  found to
        be a nuisance under state law.  The  loss suffered by the  owner
        was  caused  by state action and not by any action  of EPA.

    •   Urea-formaldehyde foam.  The Consumer Product Safety Commis-
        sion recently banned the use of UF foam, and this has caused
        direct losses to firms who manufacture and install it.  These
        are  the kinds of losses which this report considers, but  the
                                 -8-

-------
                                    INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                    Section  I
ban came after we had concluded our research and  the  situation
was too uncertain at earlier stages to analyze.   The  losses
caused to homeowners by reduction in the value of their homes
is speculative and indirect and also does not fall within  the
scope of the study.

Asbestos insulation.  There are several pieces of legislation
proposing compensation for workers who were exposed to
asbestos on the job and have suffered health affects  as a
result. .The reason for the bills Is that neither the
insurance market nor workers' compensation now appear likely
to provide a satisfactory response to this problem.   In
addition, the government was the employer for some of the
exposed workers in its shipyards.  Obviously, this is not
related to any EPA action.  However, the problem  of school
districts having to identify and remove insulation in their
schools pursuant to EPA regulation is mentioned in this study.
                         -9-

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Section I
                        C.  OTHER INFORMATION

    Information for this study was collected from November 1978
through May 1982.  During this time, significant legislative and
agency activity relevant to this study occurred — including the pro-
posal and elimination of government indemnification programs, the pre-
sentation of major indemnification claims under § 15 of FIFRA, and the
initiation of new federal regulatory and budget policies that will
affect the future consideration of indemnification programs by
Congress.  This report is largely up-to-date on such issues.  However,
the political backdrop to regulatory relief is still changing, and the
indemnification issue primarily involves policy judgments affected by
evolving considerations.
                                 -10-

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Section II
                 II.  BACKGROUND ON INDEMNIFICATION


                                                                Page

A.    The Study Mandate Under TSCA § 25(a)	12

      1.  The Statutory Provision	12
      2.  Meaning and Origin of the Study Mandate	12

B.    History of Indemnification by the Government	15

      1.  Traditional Limitations 	  15
      2.  Examples of Government Indemnification	16

Footnotes	22
                                -11-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Section II
               A.   THE STUDY MANDATE  UNDER  TSCA  §  25(a)

 1.  The  Statutory Provision

    Section  25(a) of TSCA provides:

                 (a) INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY.—The
               Administrator shall conduct a study  of  all
               Federal laws administered by  the Administrator
               for the purpose of determining whether  and
               under what conditions,  if any, indemnification
               should be accorded any  person as a result of
               any action taken by the Administrator under
               any such law.  The study shall-
                   (1) include an estimate  of the  probable
                 cost of any Indemnification programs which
                 may be recommended;
                   (2) include an examination of all  viable
                 means of financing the cost of  any recom-
                 mended indemnification; and
                   (3) be completed and submitted  to
                 Congress within two  years  from  the effec-
                 tive date of enactment of  this  Act.
               The General Accounting  Office shall  review the
               adequacy of the study submitted to Congress
               pursuant to paragraph (3) and shall  report the
               results of its review to the  Congress within
               six months of the date  such study  is submitted
               to Congress.

2.  Meaning and Origin of the Study Mandate

    The genesis of the § 25(a) study  mandate occurred In 1972 when  the
92nd Congress  enacted § 15 of FIFRA requiring EPA  to  indemnify  certain
pesticide owners suffering losses due to EPA's emergency suspension
and cancellation of a pesticide registration.    This  indemnification
provision was  supported by the House  Agriculture Committee and  Initi-
ally opposed by the Senate, but the Senate  ultimately accepted  the
provision in order to get the pesticide bill passed.2

    Subsequently, in the 93rd Congress the  Senate  attempted to  repeal
the pesticide  indemnification provision and prevent its inclusion in
toxic substances control legislation.-*  The attempt was a part  of a
Senate amendment to an unenacted toxic substances  control bill, which
also would have required EPA to commission  an independent study of
indemnification to be conducted by a  university  or independent
research center.^ Although TSCA did not pass during the 93rd Congress,
it was enacted in 1976 during the second session of the 94th Congress
and included the study mandate noted  above.^
                                 -12-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section II
     While the term "indemnification"  was not expressly defined in
 §  25(a)  aa  enacted,  a predecessor bill which passed the Senate defined
 "indemnity"  as:

               .  •  .  any payment made  to a person as reim-
               bursement for loss or damage other than a
               payment made in accordance with the judgment
               of any Court in an action brought at common
               law  or under the [Federal Tort Claims Act].6

      Thus,  the  "indemnification" with which this study is concerned
 Involves  compensation or reimbursement for loss or damage incurred by
 any  person  as a  result of an action by the EPA Administrator in admin-
 istering  Federal laws.  Excluded from this definition is any payment
 that the  party might receive from the government through a judgment in
 a  court  of  law.  Also excluded are a  variety of federal government
 payments  which do  not Involve reimbursement for loss, such as:

      •   Payments to government employees or contractors for public
          services.

      •   Entitlement payments and subsidies to particular groups,
          Including  the poor,  the elderly, veterans,  and farmers.
          Sometimes  these benefits take the form of loans, loan
          guarantees,  or tax credits.

      In  addition,  some federal programs are designed to cover the
 risk of various losses and provide reimbursement payments out of an
 insurance reserve  funded by premiums  paid by the parties protected
 from potential loss.   The federal government is involved in insurance
 or reinsurance covering crops,  floods,  crime,  urban riots, nuclear
 disasters, bank or savings and loan failures,  war risks, mortgages,
 health and medical,  unemployment and  exports.    To the extent that
 payouts are  funded by premiums, instead of by payments from the
 federal treasury,  these insurance programs are distinct from govern-
ment  indemnification.

      Similarly, restoration funds such as those available under
 Superfund which are  supported  by an "injury tax" or a surcharge on a
product or activity  related to the purpose of the fund (e.g., cleaning
up hazardous  waste sites)  are  distinct  from government
indemnification."  Furthermore, disaster relief payments or other
financial support  such as  loans or loan guarantees in emergency cir-
cumstances are not within the  scope of  government indemnification con-
templated by  this  study.   Nor  is victim compensation  or emergency
relief in environmental Impairment type situations.'

      Indemnity payments  by the federal government thus consitltute a
very  small portion of  the  overall total of government payments.  Even
among federal  mechanisms  designed to  protect against  risk, government
                                  -13-

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Section II
indemnification is only one small part, because premium-funded  federal
insurance mechanisms and restoration funds cover a wide variety of
potential loss categories.
                                 -14-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section II
           B.   HISTORY OF  INDEMNIFICATION  BY  THE  GOVERNMENT

      The  following  brief  background  information  is  documented  and
discussed  in  detail  in Appendix A  and  in  the  portions  of  this  report
covering existing EPA indemnification  programs.

1.    Traditional Limitations

      The  concept of sovereign immunity — which  bars  a  suit against
the government except with  its permission  —  provides  a  key to
understanding the question  of indemnification by  the government.
Sovereign  immunity protects  the government from being  legally  forced
to provide compensation to  injured  parties.1*-* Nevertheless, there  are
areas where,  either by constitutional  provision or by  statute,  the
government has waived its  immunity  and can be sued for money damages.
For example,  the Fifth Amendment requires  compensation when private
property is taken for public use,  and  contract claims  and  some  tort
suits against the government have  been expressly  authorized by
statute.

      Such judicial actions  for damages, however, are  narrowly  pre-
scribed, and  regulated parties usually are not paid  by the government
to comply with regulatory  requirements.  Nor  are  they  normally  compen-
sated for  the burdens of regulation or the adverse effects of  govern-
ment actions.  Although the  Federal Tort Claims Act  allows suits
against the government for operational negligence, such  as careless
driving, liability suits against the government are  not  authorized  for
negligence in performing discretionary functions  such  as promulgating
regulations.11  The government is  also protected  from  damage suits
based on misrepresentations made by government employees.1^  Further-
more, courts  have consistently refused to  interpret  statutes as
implying private rights of action  against  the government for
damages."  Moreover, the Anti-Deficiency  Act1* precludes  executive
branch employees from making a promise of  indemnification  without
an express congressional authorization and appropriation.

      These traditional limitations on indemnification for the  adverse
effects of governmental actions stem,  to a large  extent, from a fear
of creating precedents which would  require government  indemnity pay-
ments for a wide range of  regulatory activities,  and from  the belief
that situations that might require  indemnity  should  be avoided  so as
to make such  payments unnecessary.  Some of the arguments  against
paying compensation to parties injured by  regulatory activities are:

      (1)  Government could not function if it had to  compensate par-
           ties for all the  regulatory burdens which it  imposes, *

      (2)  The essential character  of  government  regulation involves
           the uncompensated adjustment of individual  rights for the
           public good;1"
                                 -15-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Section  II
       (3)   Business  risks  and  regulatory  liabilities  have  tradition-
            ally  been placed  upon  private  parties;

       (4)   Indemnification can be disruptive  of  governmental  program
            objectives;

       (5)   A decision to indemnify in  one circumstance  can set  a
            costly  precedent  requiring  compensation  payments in  many
            additional circumstances; and

       (6)   Alternative  remedial devices which avoid loss or lessen
            harm  are  usually  preferable to indemnification.*'

       Since the  enactment  of § 15 of FIFRA in 1972, no  new prospective
programs have been enacted for the purpose of compensating a  private
party  for commercial loss  due  to  anticipated  agency action.  Instead,
Congress has tended  to  put the risk of loss with the  party who  engages
In activity requiring regulation.   To  protect against unforeseeable
harm,  Congress has established procedures requiring ample  notice  to,
and participation  of,  affected parties in the development  of  regula-
tions; and  to protect against  unintended  harm, Congress has provided
for waivers and  exceptions,  as well as for timely administrative  peti-
tions  and judicial review.   Most  regulatory statutes  implemented  by
EPA contain an ample variety of these  loss avoidance  and special
relief mechanisms.   Moreover,  inquires of representatives  of
Industries  affected  by  EPA statutes disclosed no demands for  Indemni-
fication from unforeseeable  or erroneous  regulation (other than events
subject to  existing  indemnification authority).

      The option of  indemnifying  regulated parties  for  losses due to
EPA action  has received very little attention from  the  current
Congress, since  industrial losses  can  be  prevented  by relaxing  regula-
tory requirements, and  an  indemnification program could pose  an even
greater drain on the  federal budget.   The concern over  budget is  par-
ticularly evident  in the recent proposals to  Congress for  fiscal  year
1983, which would  cut back existing indemnification programs  at the
Department  of Agriculture  for  diseased livestock and  contaminated
milk.18  Last year,  Congress agreed to eliminate the  Agriculture
indemnification program for  beekeepers.1'

2.    Examples of  Government Indemnification

      a.  Indemnification Categories

          Indemnification has  been  used in a  variety  of circumstances
and for one or more  of  the following reasons:

          •    remedying inequities;
                                 -16-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section II
           •     creating  disincentives  to inappropriate  or  unreasonable
                government  action;  and

           •     creating  incentives for action by  parties outside  the
                federal government  to  facilitate achievement  of  a
                public goal.

           Some  congressional  Indemnification determinations  have
occurred after  the  fact  of  loss.   Others have Involved  prospective
programs designed as incentives or disincentives.  Most of the  equity
determinations  have been made  on a case-by-case basis,  unless a clear
and regular pattern of loss has been Identified which would  warrant an
indemnification program.20

      b.   Indemnification on Equitable Grounds

           Indemnification for  equitable reasons includes the payment
of compensation for the  taking of  private property for  public use.
Under the  Fifth Amendment of  the Constitution, a  compensable taking
occurs only when full title to property is actually expropriated, the
normal indicia  of property ownership are all destroyed, or an impor-
tant property element is expropriated  for the use of another.21 The
seizure of contraband or substances injurious to  public health  does
not constitute  a taking  for which  compensation is required.

           The Federal Tort Claims  Act,  originally passed in  19A6, par-
tially waives the government's Immunity from suit and permits negli-
gence actions to be brought against it,  except for discretionary acts,
misrepresentations, and  certain other  specific exceptions.23
Similarly, the  Tucker Act authorizes contract and other non-tort money
claims to  be brought against the government  in the Court of  Claims.24

           Some  parties injured by  government actions have  successfully
sought equitable relief  from Congress  by means of private  bills
covering specific cases.25  Sometimes  Congress refers such matters to
the Court  of Claims commissioners  for  an advisory determination, and
sometimes  it confers special jurisdiction on the  court  for a particu-
lar case.26  Examples of such  congressional  relief for  the adverse
consequences of government error include  the Mlzokami spinach case^'
and the Marlin  toys case.28  in each of  those situations,  the misrep-
resentation exception to the Federal Tort  Claims Act prevented  a
negligence action from being maintained.   In the  spinach case,  the
Mlzokami brothers were awarded more than  $300,000 in damages suffered
when the FDA incorrectly found certain  spinach to be contaminated by
the pesticide heptachlor.  In  the Marlin  toys case, more than $40,000
was awarded as  compensation for loss that  occurred when a  toy was
incorrectly listed by the CPSC as being  banned.

          The CPSC ban on children's sleepwear containing  the chemical
flame retardant Tris is a recent instance  in which Congress  has
                                 -17-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section II
 indicated  that  indemnification  can  be appropriate to correct an
 inequity.^  Although  the  first Trie  bill was vetoed by President
 Carter,  a  second bill  passed  the Senate  last  year and is awaiting
 action  by  the House.   In the  Tris case,  the CPSC had established  flam-
 mability standards  for children's sleepwear,  and many manufacturers
 met  the  requirement by using  fabrics  treated  with Tris.  When Tris was
 later determined to be carcinogenic,  a ban was imposed on further
 sales and  repurchase by the clothing  manufacturers was required.

           In most cases where no Court of Claims or Federal Tort
 Claims action is available, it  is necessary to petition Congress  for  a
 private  bill.   However, in the  cranberry case of 1959, the USDA tapped
 an existing fund without having to  go to Congress.^0  More than $8
 million  was paid to cranberry growers adversely affected by government
 publicity  concerning cranberries grown In the states of Washington and
 Oregon which were contaminated  with a dangerous herbicide.  The indem-
 nity payments compensated the growers of untainted cranberries in
 other states who were unable  to sell  their crops due to the scare over
 pesticide  contamination.

           Finally, the EPA pesticide  indemnity program under § IS of
 FIFRA is based  partially upon equitable  concepts in that compensation
 is to be paid to pesticide owners who suddenly are forced to dispose
 of stocks  of pesticides which the government  had previously
 registered.31

      c.   Disincentives to Inappropriate or Unreasonable Government
           Action

           A prospective indemnification  program can be intended as a
 disincentive to undesirable government action.   Indemnification can
 force the  government agency to  internalize the expense of losses  suf-
 fered as a result of agency action, and  thereby stimulate a more
 thorough consideration of whether or  not such losses can be avoided.
 Often an accompanying rationale for indemnification under these cir-
 cumstances is a desire to compensate  the injured party for equitable
 reasons.

           Indemnification under § 15  of  FIFRA was intended by some as
 a disincentive  to hasty or ill-considered pesticide registration.  It
 has also been suggested that  §  15 operates as a disincentive to EPA's
 cancellation of pesticides without  the use of the "Special Rule" under
 § 15 which allows existing stocks of  pesticides to be used or sold
even after an emergency cancellation  of  the registration.

          The Equal Access to Justice Act,  passed in 1980, is a recent
example of a statute designed to prevent or punish unreasonable gov-
ernment action.32  it accomplishes  this  by awarding court costs and
attorneys'  fees to successful small business  litigants (in court and
informal agency adjudications),  unless the agency can prove that its
action was "substantially justified."
                                 -18-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Section  II
          A  similar  disincentive  provision  exists  under  §  113  of  the
Clean Air Act  which  authoriEes  a  court  to award  attorneys'  fees and
costs if EPA brings  an  unreasonable Clean Air  enforcement  action.33

      d.  Indemnification as an Incentive for  Action  by  Parties Out-
          side the Federal Government to Facilitate Achievement of a
          Public Goal

          Prospective indemnity programs may be  established as incen-
tives to prompt action  by parties other than Federal  agencies. An
indemnity program can also facilitate achievement  of  public goals by
removing disincentives  to outside party action.

          There are  numerous agricultural indemnity programs that
operate as incentives.-^  Pesticide problems are the  basis  for most of
the agricultural indemnity programs.  Two of them, in addition to
FIFRA § 15,  address  the problem of a farmer caught between  the con-
flicting goals of using pesticides to increase productivity and pro-
tecting the  public food supply  from contamination  by  dangerous
residues.  When food is barred  from the market because of unacceptable
pesticide residues, notwithstanding the farmer's lawful  use of such
pesticides,  part of  the loss has been shifted  to the  government.

          The  beekeepers program compensated for damage  done to bees
by pesticides  developed as substitutes for DDT.35  xhe program was
officially terminated after Congress apparently decided  last summer
that twenty  years was sufficient time to adjust  to the cancellation of
DDT.

          The  dairy  indemnity program compensates  dairy  farmers pre-
vented from  marketing milk with unacceptable pesticide residues.36  At
one point dairy farmers received $350,000 a year as compensation  for
such losses.  Apparently, current pesticides are not  as  persistent and
do not prevent milk  from being  marketed as often.  Only  $40,000-
$50,000 a year has been paid in recent years.  However,  a   major con-
tamination incident in Hawaii this year may overwhelm the program with
millions of  dollars in claims.

          The  cranberry case mentioned above is a  fourth instance of
pesticide-related indemnities.

          The animal disease program is the oldest and most  costly
agricultural indemnity program.3'  it accompanies  and supports a
cluster of USDA programs aimed  at the eradication  of  particular
livestock diseases.  The money  paid for destruction of diseased and
exposed animals serves as an incentive for farmers to cooperate with
the program.  Between 1970 and  1981, more than $180 million  of indem-
nities were  paid under the diseased livestock  program.

          Another health-related, but non-agricultural,  indemnity
program is associated with the  swine flu vaccine.38   AS  an  incentive
                                 -19-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section  II
 to  get  vaccine  manufacturers  to  produce  swine  flu  vaccine,  the  govern-
 ment  accepted some  of  the  liability  risk  of  the  immunization  program.
 In  a  complicated arrangement,  the  government agreed  to  accept the  vac-
 cine  manufacturers' potential  strict product liability  for  personal
 injuries due to the vaccine.   Under  this  scheme, an  injured victim is
 permitted  to sue only  the  federal  government under state  tort law.
 Later,  if  negligence is proved,  then the  government  can in  turn
 recover from the parties responsible for  the negligence.  In  effect,
 the federal government has accepted  the  product  liability exposure of
 the vaccine manufacturers  for  liability  in excess  of that for negli-
 gence.  Thus far, more than $40  million  of awards  or settlements have
 been  made  by the government under  the  program, out of more  than 4,000
 claims  seeking  $2.95 billion.

           The Arts and Artifacts Indemnity Act enables  the  federal
 government to indemnify American museums  for losses  incurred  in exhi-
 biting  international loaned art  or artifacts.  *  Under  the  Act  the
 program my not  obligate more than  $400 million at  any one time  and
 there is a limit of $50 million  per  exhibit.  Although  no indemnity
 payments have yet been made, the fact  that museums do not have  to
 purchase private insurance for the amount covered  by the  federal
 Indemnification program has saved  an estimated $800  million in
 insurance  premiums as of the summer  of 1981.

           Indemnification clauses  In government defense contracts^
 are similar in  many ways to the  Arts and Artifacts Program.   Although
 the Anti-Deficiency Act usually  prevents  an Executive Branch  official
 from  promising  to pay a contingent and uncertain liability, Congress
 and the President have made exceptions for contracts that "facilitate
 the national defense" and are  "unusually hazardous or nuclear in
 nature." Although such contractual indemnification clauses  have fre-
 quently been used, no claims have  actually been paid by the government
 to date.

           Indemnification for government contractors is a matter of
 current congressional concern.   Objections to classifying certain
 activities as "unusually hazardous,"  resulted  in 1981 legislation  per-
mitting an Indemnification clause  in NASA contracts  for the benefit of
 space shuttle users.  It has also  led  to an interagency task  force,
 co-sponored by  the Office of Federal Procurement Policy and NASA,
which recently  completed a draft report  recommending expansion  of
 indemnification authority to include catastrophic  losses  beyond those
covered by reasonably available  insurance but not  "unusually  hazard-
ous." There is  also a proposed bill  to indemnify all suppliers  of  pro-
ducts to the government.

          Indemnification has also been used as an incentive  to
encourage  prompt private-party clean up of oil spills or  hazardous
waste spills.^  Section 311(1)  of the Clean Water Act  encourages  an
Innocent discharger to assist in clean up by promising  to reimburse
                                 -20-

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Section II
him for the reasonable costs involved.  The Outer Continental Shelf
Lands Act Amendments of 1978,  the Deepwater Port Act of 1974 and the
Trans-Alaska Pipeline Authorization Act all contain provisions per-
taining to oil spills that are similar in basic design to § 311.  The
Comprehensive Environmental Response, Compensation and Liability Act
(CERCLA) contains provisions relating to hazardous substance spills.
While CERCLA contains no provision identical to § 311(1), a similar
result is accomplished under § lll(a) which provides that the
President may pay claims for necessary response costs incurred by any
person as a result of carrying out the national contingency plan, so
long as such costs are approved under the plan and are certified by
the responsible federal official.

          Another incentive program is that under § 202(a)(3) of the
Clean Water Act which authorizes EPA to provide 100 percent funding of
modification or replacement costs of failed municipal wastewater
treatment facilities using innovative or alternative technology.^
This provision acts as an insurance policy designed to encourage use
of new and risky technology.
                                 -21-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section II
                       FOOTNOTES TO SECTION II

             the  Federal Environmental Pesticides Control Act of 1972,
P.L. 92-516, 86  Stat. 973, contained, in Section 15, a provision
amending FIFRA,  the Federal Insecticide, Fungicide, and Rodenticide
Act.  P.L. 80-104, 61 Stat. 163.
         §  15 indemnities provision was part of H.R. 10729.  See
H.R. Rep. No. 92-511, 92d Cong., 1st Sess. (1971) (accompanying
H.R. 10729).  Two Senate Committees amended H.R. 10729 to strike out
the pesticide Indemnity provision, and the Senate as a whole approved
this change.  S. Rep. No. 92-838, 92d Cong., 2d Sess. (1972).  Specif-
ically, the Senate Committee on Agriculture and Forestry adopted the
amendment, and the Senate Commerce Committee on June 23, 1972 reported
the legislation out without any changes to the Agriculture and
Forestry Committee's decision against indemnities.  The Senate on
September 26, 1972, passed H.R. 10729 in this form.  However, the
pesticide indemnification provision was restored in Conference and
became law in 1972.  Committee of Conference, S. Rep. No. 92-1540, 92d
Cong., 2d Sess. (1972).
         Senate toxic substances control bill originally made no men-
tion of indemnification.  However, this bill (S. 426) was amended by
the Senate to provide that no indemnity payments should be made under
TSCA or under § 15 of FIFRA.  119 Cong. Rec. 24494-95 (1973).  See
also Toxic Substances Control Act of 1973;  Hearings on S. 426 and
Amendments 1, 8, and 9 Before the Subcomm. on Environment of the
Senate Comm. on Commerce, 93d Cong., 1st Sess. (1973) and Toxic
Substance Control Act of 1973; S. Rep. No. 93-254, 93d Cong., 1st
Sess. (1973).

    ^S. 426 as reported out of the Senate Commerce Committee contained
the described provisions of Senator Phillip Hart's Amendment No. 9 on
indemnification.  The bill passed the Senate on July 18, 1973 with
this provision intact.
         House toxic substances control bill in the 93rd Congress made
no mention of indemnification, and no bill emerged from Conference in
the 93rd Congress.  See Toxic Substances Control Act of 1973;  Report
of the House Comm. on Interstate & Foreign Commerce, H.R. Rep. No.
93-360, 93d Cong., 1st Sess. (1973).  Neither H.R. 5087 nor H.R. 5350
contained any indemnification provisions.

    The idea of a study of indemnification reemerged in the first ses-
sion of the 94th Congress in 1975.  The Senate bill (S. 776) again
called for an independent study of indemnification but, unlike the
amended version of S. 426 in the 93rd Congress, did not attempt to bar
indemnification under TSCA or under § 15 of FIFRA.  A House bill (H.R.
7229) contained a provision requiring a study by the General Account-
ing Office (GAO) of Indemnification under all laws administered by
                                 -22-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section II
 EPA.   See Toxic  Substances  Control  Act:   Hearings on H.R.  7229,
 H.R.  75A8, and H.R.  7664  Before  the Subcomm.  on Consumer Protection  &
 Finance  of the Corem.  on Interstate  & Foreign  Commerce,  94th  Cong., 1st
 Sees.  (Serial No.  94-41)  (1975).  H.R.  7229,  H.R. 7548,  and  H.R.  10318
 contained indemnification provisions,  but H.R.  7664 did  net.  There
 was  no debate on the  floor  of  either body in  1975 on the issue of
 indemnification, and  again  nothing  emerged from Conference.

     In 1976,  during  the second session  of the 94th Congress, the  House
 bill  (H.R. 14032)  contained  the  § 25(a)  provision that  was finally
 adopted  into  law.  Toxic  Substances Control Act;   Report by  the House
 Comm.  on Interstate & Foreign  Commerce  [H.R.  14032],  94th  Cong.,  2d
 Sess.  (1976).  The Senate bill (S.  3149)  contained a similar section,
 with  the difference  that  the GAO, Instead of  the  EPA, was  to conduct
 the  study. S. 3149 was cleaned-up  version of S.  776.   Toxic
 Substances Control Act:   Report  of  the  Senate Comm. on  Commerce [H.R.
 14032],  94th  Cong., 2d Sess. (1976).    In Conference, the  Senate  bill
 was  largely adopted,  although  the House  indemnification  study provi-
 sion was used instead of  the language  from the  Senate bill.   Toxic
 Substances Control Act;   H.R.  Rep.  No.  94-1679, 94th Cong.,  2d Sess.
 100-101  (1976).  Again, there  was no debate in  either the  Senate  or
 the House focusing on § 25(a).  The bill  passed both bodies  on
 September 28, 1976 and was  signed into  law by President  Ford on
 October  11, 1976.  P.L. 94-469,  15  U.S.C.  §§  2601 et  seq.

    ^Senator Hart's Amendment  No. 9 to  S.  426,  supra note  4,  included
 this definition  of indemnity.  A  review  of case  decisions and secon-
 dary sources defining "indemnity" and "indemnification"  reveals that
 the terms "indemnity," "compensation,"  "contribution,"  and "insurance"
 are closely related, and  frequently one term  is used  to  define
 another.   Nevertheless, each term has a distinct  legal meaning that
 sets it  apart from the other terms.

    "Compensation" is the broadest  of the  four  terms.   ISA C.J.S.
 "Compensation" at 102 (1967);  Black's Law Dictionary 256 (5th ed.
 1979).   It  refers to a transaction  between two  or more  persons in
 which  one  person restores another person  to his former  position,
 usually  through  the payment of money.  In  the case of liability for
 physical  injuries, compensation involves  the  payment of  money to  make
 the injured person whole, i.e., through reimbursement for  medical
 expenses,  lost earnings,  etc.  Compensation may also relate  to payment
 for services rendered, or for  property taken  or destroyed.

    The  right of "indemnity" may arise either in  equity  (to  avoid
 unjust enrichment) or in  contract,  where  one  party obligates himself
 to insure  a loss or to discharge a  duty or obligation.   In the context
 of an equitable  remedy, "indemnity"  is a  right which inures  to a  per-
 son who has discharged a  duty  owed  by him,  bujt which should  have  been
 discharged  by another person.  Restatement of Restitution  §  76; 41
Am. Jur.   2d "Indemnity" § 1, at 687  (1968); American Mutual  Liability
                                 -23-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section II
 Insurance Co. v. Reed Cleansers,  265 Minn. 503,  122 N.W.2d 178, 182
 (1963).   To illustrate,  an employer orders an employee to repossess
 the  car  of a third person.  In fact the employer had no right to
 repossess the car, and thus the repossession amounted to a conversion
 of  the car.  The employee is liable to the third party for his tor-
 tious  act in taking the  car.  However, since the employee acted within
 the  scope of his employment, he would be entitled to indemnification
 from his employer who is primarily liable to the third party for the
 conversion of the car.

     In the context of "indemnity" as a contractual remedy, the insur-
 ance situation is a common example.  42 C.J.S.  "Indemnity" § 1 at 564,
 and  §  3  at 566 (1944); Ballantine's Law Dictionary at 608; Black's
 Law  Dictionary at 692.  By contract, the Insurer agrees to indemnify
 the  insured against loss or liability.  While the insured is liable to
 the  third party for the  loss which the third party sustained, the
 insurance carrier by contract has obligated itself either to pay the
 third  party for the loss, or to reimburse the Insured for the amount
 which  he paid to compensate the third party.  In this instance, the
 contract Imposes the responsibility upon the insurance carrier and
 creates  the right of Indemnity for the insured.

     "Contribution" is the right of one who pays  more than his propor-
 tionate  share of an obligation to be compensated by the others who
 were also liable.   Restatement of Restitution §  81 and Comment b;
 Black's  Law Dictionary 297 (5th ed. 1979);  Shannon v. Massachusetts
 Bonding  & Insurance Co.,  62 F. Supp. 532,  537 (W.D.  La. 1945).
 Examples of such parties  are joint tortfeasors or joint obligors on a
 draft.   Contribution differs from indemnity in  that the liability Is
 shared,  rather than the  whole burden being shifted from one party to
 another.

     "Insurance"  is simply a contract by which the insurer undertakes
 to indemnify the insured  against  loss arising from a specific
 event.   44  C.J.S.  "Insurance" § Ib at 473 (1945);  Physicians' Defense
 Co.  v. Cooper.  199 F.  576,  578 (9th Clr.  1912);  Black's Law DictionaFy
 at 721.   Ballantine's Law Dictionary at 642;  Jordan v.  Group Health
 Ass'n, 107  F.2d  239,  245  (1939).   The contract of insurance has three
 basic  elements.   First,  there must be consideration or value given to
 the  Insurer in exchange  for its obligation to pay.   In most instances
 consideration will take  the form  of the premiums which the Insured
 pays on  his policy.   Second,  there must be  a risk which is unknown or
 contingent,  and  against which the insured  is  protected.  The risk may
 be in  the  form of  harm to the insured himself or of  liability to a
 third  party.   Finally, there  must be indemnity,  i.e.,  a specified sum
 to be  paid  by the  insurer in  the  event  loss  Is suffered from the
occurrence  of the  event or contingency specified in  the contract.
Thus, by  contract  responsibility  for payment  of  the  loss is shifted
from the  insured  to  the insurance carrier.
                                 -24-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section II
     ^Federal  Crop  Insurance  Corporation,  7  U.S.C.  §§  1501  et  seq.;
 National  Flood  Insurance  Program,  42 U.S.C.  §§  4001 et  seq. ;  Federal
 Crime  Insurance, 12  U . S . C . §§  1749 bbb-lOa  et seq.; Urban  Property
 Protection  and  Reinsurance Act,  12 U.S.C. §§  1749  bbb et seq.;  Nuclear
 Energy Liability Insurance,  42 U.S.C.  §§  2210 et seq.;  Federal  Deposit
 Insurance,  12 U.S.C. §§ 1811 et  seq. (FDIC),  12 U.S.C.  §§  1725  et seq.
 (FSLIC),  and  12 U.S.C. §§ 1781 et  seq.  (share insurance for credit
 unions);  war  risks insurance,  46 U.S.C. §§  1281 et seq. (marine war
 risk insurance) and  49 U.S.C.  §§ 1531  et  seq. (air war  risk insur-
 ance); mortgage and  housing  insurance,  12 U.S.C. § 1703 (insurance of
 institutions which finance housing); 12 U.S.C.  §§  1706c et seq. (mort-
 gage insurance); 12  U.S.C. §§  1736 et  seq.  (war housing insurance); 12
 U.S.C. §§ 1747  et seq. (insurance  of investments in rental housing);
 42 U.S.C. §§  1471 et seq. (federal housing); 46 U.S.C.  §§  1271  et seq.
 (ship  mortgage  insurance); health  and  medical Insurance, 5 U.S.C.
 §§ 8901 et  seq.; 42 U.S.C. §§  1395 et  seq.; unemployment insurance, 45
 U.S.C. §§ 351 et seq.; Export-Import Bank tangible property insurance,
 12 U.S.C. § 635.  See also Overseas Private Investment  Corporations 's
 insurance of corporate Investments abroad,  22 U.S.C.  §  2191.
     See Appendix B on Alternatives to Indemnification, page B-6.

    9 Recently, Congress has been willing  to assist  industry in
the face of potentially enormous claims due to personal or property
injury by establishing liability limits and assisting with payment of
the claims.  The Comprehensive Environmental Response, Compensation
and Liability Act of 1980, P.L. 96-510, 94 Stat. 2767, establishes
liability limits for damages and cleanup  costs associated with  inac-
tive chemical disposal sites and chemical spills and it establishes a
fund (financed primarily by industry) to  facilitate, among other
matters, cleanup and remedial activity where fault  or responsibility
cannot be determined.  Recently proposed  legislation in both the House
and the Senate involving occupational injuries related to asbestos
would utilize the same method:  a limit on liability and an industry
financed fund to cover claims.  See H.R.  5224, sponsored by Rep.
Millicent Fenwick (R-N.J.) and H.R. 5735, sponsored by Rep. George
Miller (R-Cal.).

    In both the case of chemical discharges and asbestos injuries,
however, there is an apparent congressional attitude that those per-
sons responsible for damages and injuries should absorb the costs
involved.  Government assistance is justified because it primarily
benefits the public or the class of injured persons, rather than
industry.  The prevailing attitude appears to be that the government
may consider stepping in where traditional market incentives and reme-
dial systems (e.g. , insurance, liability  law, judicial administration
and resolution of disputes) fail to address effectively a significant
and widespread problem.  An additional motivating factor involving
asbestos injury claims is that the government has also been an
employer of asbestos exposed workers, particularly  in public shipyards
during World War II.
                                 -25-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Section  II
    A  legislative assistant  to Representative Millicent  Fenwick who  is
familar with  the current debate  over  proposed asbestos legislation
thought that  the primary purpose  of such  legislation  is  to  assist the
worker exposed  to asbestos.  If  this  results in  underwriting  or
limiting industry costs to some  extent, she  thought it would  be
acceptable to Congress if that were the only way to provide the needed
assistance.  Both industry and the workers face  huge  legal  costs and
uncertainty in  the court system.  The worker who is injured is often
compensated after he dies, loses  a significant amount of the  award in
legal  fees, and may often be barred from  recovery entirely  by state
law which is not designed to handle claims resulting  from injury over
a 20-  to 30-year period.  The evidence suggests  that  the majority of
exposure cases  have yet to appear and the problem for Industry, the
courts and the worker will become significantly  larger in the years  to
come.                         G

    See also §  301 (e) of CERCLA which mandated a study concerning com-
mon law and statutory compensation remedies  for  harm  to  man and the
environment caused by release of hazardous substances, and  Six Case
Studies of Compensation for Toxic Substances Pollution;   Alabama,
California, Michigan, Missouri, New Jersey, and  Texas, Congressional
Research Service Report for the Senate Committee on Environment and
Public Works, 96th Cong., 2d Sess. (June  1980) (Serial No.  96-13).

    ^Appendix A, page A-2.

    1 * Appendix A, page A-4.

    ^Appendix A, page A-6.
            Eastport Steamship Corp. v. United States, 178 Ct. Cl.
599, 608-11 (1967) (damages denied in claim against Maritime Commis-
sion for an alleged abuse of its discretion to grant a license or
approval.  The Court of Claims referred to the "persistent refusal by
the federal legislature to permit damage claims against  the United
States resulting from wrongful regulatory activity").

    1431 U.S.C. 665(a), 41 U.S.C. ll(a).

    15Andrus v. Allard. 444 U.S. 51, 100 S. Ct. 318, 326  (1979)  (5th
amendment taking case).

    "id..

    l?Some additional arguments against compensation are:

        (7)   Parties affected by government regulations  should  be
              encouraged to foresee and prevent or mitigate the  poten
              tially negative effects of those regulations;
                                 -26-

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Section II
        (8)   An Executive Branch promise to indemnify In the future
              at an unknown cost would interfere with the legislative
              prerogative to authorize and appropriate money;

        (9)   Money damages are often not an appropriate or effective
              remedy for harms due to regulatory activities;

        (10)  Private parties should not be paid for compliance with
              health and safety regulations.

    *"Appendix A, page A-8.

    *^Appendix A, page A-8.

    2^A prime example of the use of an indemnification program to deal
with recurring loss situations is the Federal Tort Claims Act.  Once a
pattern or a sufficient number of loss incidents becomes clear,
Congress will usually consider establishing a regular mechanism to
handle the claims.

    ^Appendix A, page A-7.

    22Appendlx A, page A-7.

    23Appendix A, page A-2.

    ^Appendix A, page A-15.

    25Appendix A, page A-12.

    2^Appendix A, page A-15.

    27Appendix A, page A-20.

    28Appendix A, page A-21.

    2^Appendix A, page A-22.

    30Appendix A, page A-20.

    31Report, infra page 30.

    32Report, infra page 67.

    33Report, infra page 63.

    34Appendix A, page A-18.

    35Appendix A, page A-19.
                                 -27-

-------
 36
  'Appendix A,  page A-19.


37Appendix A,  page A-18.

•10
JOAppendix A,  page A-23.


39Appendix A,  page A-25.


*°Appendix A,  page A-26.


^Report, infra page 75.


A2Report, infra page 50.
                                         INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                         Section II
                            -28-

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Section III
                  III.  EVALUATION OF EPA PROGRAMS
A.  Criteria  for Evaluating the Need for Indemnification
    Within EPA Programs	   30

    I.  General Nature of the Criteria	   30
    2.  Specific Factors	   30

B.  Indemnification Under § 15 of FIFRA	   33

    1.  The Existing Program.	   33
    2.  Extension of FIFRA § 15 to New Situations	   46

C.  Indemnification Under § 202(a)(3) of the Clean Hater Act.  .   53

    1.  The Existing Program	   53
    2.  Possible Modifications of the Existing Program	   58
    3.  Possible Applications of the § 202(a)(3) Model
          in Other EPA Programs	   60

D.  Indemnification Under § 113(b) of the Clean Air Act ....   66

    1.  Legislative History and Background	   66
    2.  Application to Date	   71
    3.  Summary Assessment of § 113(b)	   74
    4.  The Applicability of the § 113(b) Model to
          Other EPA Statutes	   76

E.  Indemnification Pursuant to § 311(1) of the
      Clean Water Act	   78

    1.  Legislative History And Background	   78
    2.  Application To Date	   84
    3.  Summary Assessment of 311(1)	   91
    4.  The Applicability of § 311(1) to Other EPA Programs  .  .   93

Footnotes	   95
                                -29-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
              A.   CRITERIA  FOR  EVALUATING  THE  NEED  FOR
                   INDEMNIFICATION  WITHIN EPA PROGRAMS

 1.  General Nature Of  The Criteria

    Consideration  was  given in  this  study  to developing a general rule
 or  formula for  deciding whether indemnification  would  be warranted in
 a particular  circumstance.   After  efforts  at logical analysis,  deduc-
 tion of patterns from  previous  indemnification incidents, and use of
 tentative formulas tested by application to actual  cases and to
 hypothetical  situations, it was concluded  that a formula approach
 would be extremely complex  and  probably ineffective.   Thus,  while
 general criteria and relevant factors  for  analysis  were identified,  no
 clear-cut and automatic formula was  developed.  Examples of  past
 indemnities for the consequences of  government regulations were too
 few and varied  to  provide conclusive patterns  of important criteria.
 Precise indemnity  determinants  also  cannot be  derived  theoretically
 because real  cases appear to depend  on unpredictable combinations of
 factors.  All of the actual indemnity  situations, and  particularly
 those involving equitable considerations seem  to be dependent upon the
 facts of an individual situation.

        What  follows,  therefore, is  not a  mathematically precise  for-
 mula that can be used automatically  to decide  when  indemnification
 should be afforded a party  who  has suffered a  loss.  It is instead a
 list and brief description  of criteria that we found to be most useful
 in evaluating the  situations that  we studied.  Our  conclusions  about
 the way these factors have  worked  in specific  instances may  be  found
 with the other conclusions  in Section IV,  infra.  In evaluating these
 specific situations the factors either supporting or weighing against
 indemnification were assessed.   Then,  the  factors supporting indem-
 nification were balanced against those weighing  against indemnifica-
 tion.  Generally,  we found  that many of the factors involved an
 enormous range of  possibilities and  are often  interrelated with other
 factors.

 2.  Specific Factors

    a.  The Justification for Indemnification

        The balancing of arguments for and against  indemnification may
be expected to vary depending on the overall objective  intended.   The
strength and nature of the  justification for indemnification is a key
element in deciding whether  to  grant it.   Although  many indemnity
programs appear to  have multiple goals, there  are three possible  cate-
gories of reasons  for indemnification:

        •   Equity:  Equitable  considerations  may favor after-the-fact
            indemnification  when the government  is  "responsible"  for
            the loss or has  created an expectation  that the  government
                                  r30-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
             should  pay for the loss.  Important considerations
             include:   whether the loss was within an expected scope of
             business  risk, whether the risk was insurable,  whether the
             event  causing loss was caused in part by the injured
             party,  and if the loss resulted from reliance on the
             government,  whether such reliance was reasonable.  Another
             equity  aspect is whether the party had procedural due
             process.   This usually concerns opportunities to comment
             on  or  challenge the agency decision before the loss
             occurs.

         •    Disincentive;  Indemnification may be intended to discour-
             age certain  government action,  tinder this category,
             equity  considerations involving the nature or existence of
             a loss  would be less0important, since the major purpose
             would be  to  prevent agency action causing losses rather
             than subsequently remedying any inequities.   Key con-
             siderations  are whether such a disincentive  is  really
             needed  and whether a practically effective disincentive
             can be  structured which would not involve undesirable side
             effects.

         •    Subsidy or incentives;   Indemnities may be used as subsidy
             payments  for certain parties or financial incentives to
             encourage or permit a government objective or policy.
             Under this category,  too,  equity considerations would be
             less important, since the  major purpose would be to
             encourage action by parties outside the federal govern-
             ment.  Again, an important issue is whether  an  incentive
             is  really necessary and workable.

    b.   Need for an Anticipatory Indemnification Program

         A useful distinction in the indemnity analysis is whether the
problem  can  be  dealt  with on a case-by-case basis or whether it
requires an  indemnification program.   The factors relevant  to this
threshold question are relatively easy to apply in that  three possible
considerations  may  support the establishment of a program.   First,
there may be a  need for  a strong  incentive to influence  behavior.
Second,  a program can usually provide  much faster processing of claims
and payment  than an ad hoc approach.   Third, an institutionalized
response may be  required in order efficiently to handle  frequent,
similar  claims.

    c.   Availability  of  Alternatives to Indemnification

        This appears  to  be a very important factor in deciding whether
or not to provide indemnification to deal with an alleged problem.
Consideration must be given to whether compensation is already
available from  an existing mechanism such as a lawsuit under the
                                 -31-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 Federal  Tort  Claims  Act.   Also,  there  may be relief mechanisms  such  as
 exemptions  and  waivers  which  could  be  used to avoid loss  and  these may
 be  viewed as  a  preferable  alternative  to  indemnification.   (Alterna-
 tives  to indemnification are  discussed in detail in Appendix  B,  infra.)

     d.   Impact  on Other Policy Objectives

         Another important  factor is whether indemnification would sup-
 port or  conflict with other program objectives or legislation.
 Indemnification cannot  be  viewed in isolation.  Its usefulness  in a
 particular  situation must  be  evaluated in light of potential  negative
 side effects  or related benefits.

     e.   Legislative  Predetermination

         This  factor  concerns  whether Congress has already  considered
 the  issue of  compensation  or  other  remedies in the situation  at  hand
 and  expressed a position that should be viewed as determinative.
 Alternatively,  there may be relevant but  inconclusive  indications of
 congressional attitude  that should  be  considered.

     f.   Cost  of Indemnities

         The dollar costs of indemnification must be compared  to  the
 overall  benefits of  providing indemnities.   An indemnity payout  may  be
 unacceptably  expensive  to  administer.   Indemnification cost estimates
 may  also be too unpredictable or speculative.   However, there are a
 variety  of ways in which the  cost to the  government can be  contained,
 deferred, or  shared, though they may result In less than full
 indemnity.  Cost estimates may be more concrete if based upon analysis
 of the nature and frequency of losses  that  have already occurred,
 rather than upon abstract  predictions.  Consideration  should  also be
 given to whether an  Indemnity payment  would establish  a precedent for
 indemnification that could not readily be  distinquished.

    g.   Ability to Finance and Administer

         The feasibility and problems of administering  and  financing
 indemnification In particular circumstances should be  assessed.
 Similar  to the  issue of dollar costs,  administrative and financing
 difficulties  must be compared to the potential benefits of  an indem-
 nity mechanism.

         Indemnification payments need  to be financed and administered
 in a manner that does not  interfere  unacceptably with  the administra-
 tion of  other programs.  The choice  among  the  many ways that  a program
can be financed  must be made carefully so  that it furthers  the goals
of the indemnity programs and the underlying mission of the agency.
Failure  to choose a  financing mechanism at  the time the indemnity
program  is established  may seriously undermine it,  particularly  if it
 is Intended as  an incentive.
                                 -32-

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Section III
               B.  INDEMNIFICATION UNDER § 15 OF FIFRA

1.  The Existing Program1

    a.  Introduction

        Section 15 of FIFRA provides for the indemnification of owners
of a pesticide who suffer economic loss from the suspension and subse-
quent cancellation of the pesticide's registration.  Section 15 was
first enacted as part of the Federal Environmental Pesticide Control
Act of 1972 (FEPCA),2 which amended earlier versions of FIFRA.3
Indemnification has been retained without change in the 1975, 1978,
and 1980 versions of the Act.^  The legislative history of the § 25(a)
indemnification-study mandate shows that Congress was interested in
the type of indemnification represented by § 15 of FIFRA.

        Under § 15, indemnity for the cost of the pesticide must be
paid by EPA to any pesticide owner in those rare circumstances where
the owner can show that:

        (a) The pesticide registration was suspended on the ground
            that it posed an imminent hazard;

        (b) It was subsequently cancelled;

        (c) The suspension or cancellation of a registration caused a
            loss to the owner of the pesticide; and

        (d) If the claimant is the pesticide producer, that it
            notified EPA or discontinued production once It learned of
            facts giving rise to the need for the cancellation.

Section 15 also Includes a "Special Rule" under which EPA may avoid
causing economic losses by providing a reasonable time for use or
disposal of a suspended and cancelled pesticide.^

         No prior government program had ever provided indemnification
to manufacturers of potentially hazardous products (automobiles, toys,
or pharmaceutlcals, for example).^  However, government indemnities to
farmers whose products have been destroyed or determined to be danger-
ous to health are common.  These have included payments to cranberry
growers,^ beekeepers,^ farmers with pesticide-contaminated milk,' and
farmers with diseased livestock.10  Section 15 substantially expanded
the traditional agricultural indemnification subsidies by authorizing
indemnification of manufacturers and sellers of pesticides, In addi-
tion to farmers and other and users of pesticides.
                                 -33-

-------
                                        INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                        Section III
b.  Statutory Language

    Section 15 of FIFRA, 7 U.S.C. § 136, provides:

     SEC. 15.  INDEMNITIES.
         (a) REQUIREMENT.—If—
            (1) the Administrator notifies a regis-
         trant that he has suspended the registration of
         a pesticide because such action is necessary to
         prevent an imminent hazard;^
            (2) the registration of the pesticide is
         canceled as a result of a final determination
         that the use of such pesticide will create an
         imminent hazard;  and
            (3) any person who owned any quantity of
         such pesticide Immediately before the notice to
         the registrant under paragraph (1) suffered
         losses by reason  of suspension or cancellation
         of the registration,
     the Administrator shall make an indemnity payment
     to such person, unless the Administrator finds that
     such person (1) had knowledge of facts which, in
     themselves, would have shown that such pesticide
     did not meet the requirements of section 3(c)(5)
     for registration, and (ii) continued thereafter to
     produce such pesticide without giving timely notice
     of such facts to the  Administrator.**
         (b) AMOUNT OF PAYMENT.—
            (1) IN GENERAL.—The amount of the Indemnity
         payment under subsection (a) to any person
         shall be determined on the basis of the cost of
         the pesticide owned by such person Immediately
         before the notice to the registrant referred to
         in subsection (a)(l);  except that in no event
         shall an indemnity payment to any person exceed
         the fair market value of the pesticide owned by
         such person immediately before the notice
         referred to in subsection (a)(l).
            (2) SPECIAL RULE.—Notwithstanding any other
         provision of this Act, the Administrator may
         provide a reasonable time for use or other
         disposal of such  pesticide.  In determining the
         quantity of any pesticide for which indemnity
         shall be paid under this subsection, proper
         adjustment shall  be made for any pesticide used
         or otherwise disposed of by such owner.
                             -34-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
     c.   Legislative  History  of §  15

         Indemnification was  not included in the predecessor pesticide
 laws of 1910,  1947,  or  1964.13 -j^e indemnity provision was developed
 during  19 closed  business  meetings held by the House Agriculture
 Committee to work on H.R.  4152 in February 1971.^  xhe indemnifica-
 tion section was  later  deleted from the Senate version of FEPCA passed
 in September 1972, but  a slightly revised version of the House
 Committee Print section was  included in the conference bill that
 passed  both houses in October  1972.

         Section 15 was  a focal point of the debate over FEPCA among
 members of the agricultural  community,  pesticide producers and distri-
 butors, and representatives  of environmental and consumer organiza-
 tions.*^  As enacted, the  indemnification provision largely reflected
 the position of the  House  Agriculture Committee.  However, the Confer-
 ence Committee did add  a provision denying indemnities to manufactur-
 ers, acting in bad faith,  who  withheld  information showing that their
 pesticides should not be registered.1°

     d.   Implementation  of  §  15

         (1) Overview

            Because  EPA has  never developed regulations or guidance
 documents to implement  § 15, ad hoc  claim procedures were formulated
 for the Silvex case.  To a great  extent they followed the agreement
 negotiated primarily  between EPA  and  Chevron Chemical Company.^

            Before the  Silvex  case,  the only circumstance meeting  the
 requirements for  indemnification  under  §  15 was a minor one involving
 vinyl chloride, a propellant in aerosol pesticide cans.*°  EPA paid
 three indemnity claims,  totaling  approximately $53,000,  from EPA funds
 originally allocated  to other  purposes.

            Two other emergency suspensions (Aldrin/Dieldrin and
 Heptachlor/Chlordane) occurred during the  period from 1974-1976.^  In
 both cases, existing  stocks of pesticides  were permitted to be used or
 sold, thereby  avoiding  any indemnifiable  economic loss by the owners
 of  the  pesticides.

            One claim has  been paid  to  a  fanner after the suspension
 and  cancellation  of DBCP.  It  appears that  the total value of DBCP
 claims  will not be large.*0  in addition,  depending upon the outcome
 of  the  2,4,5-T/Silvex pesticide cancellation proceedings, indemnifica-
 tion claims may also be made for  2.4,5-T and for Silvex products that
were not  cancelled by agreements.

            During the  legislative hearings,  an estimate of the value
of  nationwide  inventory of one chemical was  made at $30 million.^2
                                 -35-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
This  is  within  the  range  of  the  expected total indemnities  for  Silvex.
The amount  is approximately  equal  to  one half of the total  annual
budget  for  EPA's  Office of Pesticide  Programs.

         (2)  Funding

             No  financing  mechanism was  provided for § 15.   The  statute
states  that, when certain requirements  are met, "the Administrator
shall make  an indemnity payment,"  thus  implying that funds  are  to come
from EPA's  budget.23  However, no  corresponding budget authorization
or appropriation  has ever been provided by Congress.

             Four  potential methods of funding EPA indemnification are:

             •     Reprogramming of  Agency funds to meet indemnities  as
                  they occur;

             •     Submitting  a supplemental budget request,  following
                  use of Agency funds  previously appropriated  for other
                  purposes;

             •     Contingency budgeting  for estimated indemnities with
                  funds held  in reserve  until  needed;  or

             •     Requesting  case-by-case appropriations by  Congress in
                  EPA's annual budget, with payment deferred until
                  funds are actually appropriated.

However, none of  these options is  free  from significant practical or
policy problems and, by default, a fifth option of payments from the
Court of Claims Judgment  Fund has  occurred.

            Because it had no funds available, and no process for
obtaining them, EPA refused  the  Silvex  claims, while acknowledging
their validity.   The claimants therefore sued the government  in the
Court of Claims.  While the  settlement  of several of these  claims has
provided for payment from the Court of  Claims Judgment Fund,  some
question remains  whether  EPA will  be  required to reimburse  the  Fund.

        (3)  Silvex

            On February 28,  1979,  the registrations of many products
containing 2,4,5-T and Silvex were suspended  by emergency order (and
notice of Intent  to cancel)  because of  imminent hazards deemed  so
serious that suspension could not  await a hearing.^   This  emergency
suspension was effective  immediately.   The Silvex suspension  covered
products registered for forestry,  rights-of-way,  pasture, home  and
garden, commercial/ornamental and  turf,  and aquatic weed control uses.
(Not all of  the uses of Silvex were suspended.   It may still  be used
for rice, range,  sugar cane, orchards,  and non-crop sites.)  Silvex
                                 -36-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 was  considered an imminent threat  because new information on human
 reproductive and oncongenic risks  was made public just before the
 spring growing season,  and EPA concluded that it had to act quickly if
 it was to prevent the pesticide from being sold or used that season.

             Led by Chevron Chemical Company,  one of the largest manu-
 facturers of Silvex products,  19 registrants  subsequently entered into
 agreements with EPA which, in  effect, cancelled the registrations of
 the  horae-and-garden use Silvex pesticides. The first of these, agree-
 ments  was signed in May 1979.   The agreements stipulated that it was
 infeasible to relabel,  recover,  recycle, reprocess, or otherwise use
 the  Silvex pesticides for any  of the non-suspended uses.  This enabled
 claimants to show economic loss required by § 15(a)(3).  It precluded
 the  government from arguing that since all uses were not suspended, a
 market remained, and the loss  would only be the cost of relabeling for
 resale.

             Other 2,4,5-T and  Silvex registrants, however, opposed
 cancellation and requested a hearing.  Those  proceedings are currently
 recessed  to allow for settlement talks.

             The agreements, that  were reached  stipulated that the stat-
 utory  criteria for indemnification under § 15 had been met, estab-
 lished procedures for processing claims and formulas for calculating
 the  value of the pesticides, and confirmed EPA's statutory obligation
 to provide for disposal of the pesticides. Under the agreements, all
 claims of the registrants, distributors and retailers owning cancelled
 products  were funneled  through each registrant and presented to EPA in
 a package.   Distributors and retailers were asked to fill out claim
 affidavits and to give  a power of  attorney to the registrants to make
 their  claims to EPA.

             EPA relied  heavily on  the registrants in processing
 claims, particularly  Chevron,  which had approximately 11,000 distribu-
 tors and  retailers of lawn and garden pesticides.  Chevron mailed a
 notice to every dealer  carrying  Chevron agriculture products, telling
 them to return their  stocks of Silvex home and garden products to the
 distributor.   The distributors gave cash payments or credits to the
 dealers.   The distributors then  delivered all they had collected to
 Chevron warehouses across  the  country.   Upon  delivery, distributors
were given credits on their accounts with Chevron.

            Apparently,  the registrants had sought the agreements with
EPA to speed  processing of their indemnification claims, and in the
 belief that  indemnification would  ultimately  be paid,  even though no
 funds  for  payment were  appropriated.   They also apparently wanted to
 be able to  empty their  warehouses  of the pesticides and to get EPA to
dispose of  them quickly.   They agreed to collect claims and assist in
 processing  them,  apparently out  of  concern with protecting their busi-
ness relations  with distributors and retailers.
                                 -37-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
             Pursuant  to  the  agreements  and  to § 19 of FIFRA,  EPA
 became  responsible  for disposing  of  a  very  large percentage of the
 horae-and-garden  Silvex on  the  market.   EPA  has already disposed of the
 39  million  pounds of  solid pesticide in a hazardous waste landfill in
 Alabama.  Approximately  900,000 gallons of  liquid pesticide should be
 destroyed soon.25

             EPA  finished processing  the first Indemnification claims
 by  early 1980  and has now  reviewed the  claims presented by 15 regis-
 trants.  Even  with  the help  of the major registrants, it has  been a
 lengthy and  difficult job.   Using the  cost  formula in the agreements,
 EPA has found  approximately  $18.2 million in indemnification  claims
 for Silvex  products to be  "appropriate." The .largest portion of this
 amount  is the  $12.8 million  of appropriate  claims in the package sub-
 mitted by Chevron.                o

             After final  review of each  claims package,  EPA sent the
 registrant  a letter Indicating the amount that the Agency considered
 appropriate.   However, the letters also stated that the Agency lacked
 funds to pay the claim and did not expect to receive such funds.

             Several registrants subsequently filed suit in the Court
 of  Claims,  seeking payment from the  Court of Claims Judgment  Fund.
 The Department of Justice, representing the government, has recently
 settled seven  of the larger  claims,  for a total of $18.7 million (the
 remaining claims total less  than  $200,000).  Except for the Ag-Way
 claim, which was settled for approximately  $500,000 when EPA  had
 approved only  about $375,000,  the Justice Department's  settlements
 have been for  amounts roughly  equal  to  those found appropriate by EPA.

             Section 15 does  not define  the  "cost" for which owners are
 to  be indemnified.  The  Justice Department  questioned the pesticide
 cost-calculation formula contained in  the negotiated agreements.
 These formula  specified  that the  cost  to a  retailer or  distributor was
 100% of the  invoice price plus 15% for  handling,  and the cost to the
 manufacturer was 70% of  the  cost  to  the dealer.   The position of the
 Justice Department was that  actual cost data was  required for a calcu-
 lation of Indemnification amounts and that  the  formula  (particularly
 the  15% allowance for handling) was  not consistent with the language
 of  § 15.  However, an FBI Investigation of  actual cost  data revealed
 that in nearly every circumstance the formula in  the agreements was
 too  low and  the registrants'  claim totals,  which  sometimes exceeded
EPA's approved figure, were  also  too low.   Therefore,  in each of the
 seven settled claims, the Justice Department agreed to  the amount
 claimed.

    e.  Evaluation of §  15

        There has not been sufficient activity  under FIFRA §  15 to
evaluate its effectiveness conclusively.  However,  a start can be made
                                 -38-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 by  comparing  the  actual operation of the program to the assumptions,
 goals,  and  arguments  made before enactment.  In the  ten years since the
 debate,  some  of  the arguments have proven insubstantial,  while others
 have  taken  on new weight.

         (1) Arguments in Support of Indemnification

            (a)   Pesticide manufacturers, dealers,  and owners of
                  pesticides rely in good faith on the government's
                  pesticide registration

                  Arguments were  made during  the legislative debate on
 § 15  that indemnification would  be necessary to protect manufacturers,
 dealers, and  farmers  who rely on the validity of a  pesticide's regis-
 tration, if EPA changed its mind and canceled a registration. ^  This
 argument rests on the premise that an Innocent party has  relied, in
 good  faith  and to its detriment  on the registration.

                  The  pesticide manufacturers apparently hoped to be
 able  to  rely  on  the registration and tried to insert into the 1972
 FIFRA amendments  a provision that would use  the registration to shield
 them  from third-party liability.   They suceeded only in obtaining the
 very  conditional  language of § 3(f)(2) that  says "provided that as
 long  as  no  cancellation proceedings are in effect,  registration of a
 pesticide shall be prima facie evidence that the pesticide,  its
 labeling and  packaging comply with registration provisions of the
 Act."

                  In reality,  there is little factual basis for relying
 on  the registration of the average pesticide as conclusive proof of
 its safety.  Most  current pesticides were either "grandfathered" in
 from  previous  pesticide laws or  involve state,  rather than federal,
 registration.2'  Many registrations are granted by  the state on the
 basis of limited  test data,  with nominal review by  EPA.   Some experi-
mental use permits are not registrations.

                 Moreover,  most  pesticide manufacturers do not in
 fact  appear to rely upon the continuation of registration.   The
 registration section  (§ 3(f))  disclaims reliance.   The statutory
 requirements applied  to most existing pesticides have been relatively
 lax.28  Moreover,  in  making its  registration determination,  EPA relies
almost exclusively upon data submitted by the registration applicant.
Thus, the pesticide manufacturer  is typically relying upon its own
data, rather than  that of the  government,  when making financial deci-
sions concerning  pesticide production and inventory.

                 Nor  is there  a  basis for relying on the  indefinite
continuation of the registration.   The structure of the Act  makes
clear the intention of Congress  that  a pesticide may be cancelled
whenever new information shows that  it may be an unreasonable risk.2*
                                 -39-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
                  Farmers  may more reasonably be expected to rely on
 EPA's registration of  a pesticide.   However, farmers have a problem
 after a deregistration that  Is bigger than the loss of Inventory —
 finding a comparably  priced  substitute that is equally efficacious.
 Sometimes this  is not  immediately possible, and the fanner has to pay
 more  for a substitute  that  results  in a lower yield, at least for a
 couple of years.    Although these  costs are not addressed by the
 current indemnification program,  they are taken into account when the
 Agency makes  cancellation decisions.   FIFRA § 6(b) requires the Admin-
 istrator to consider  restricting  uses as an alternative to cancella-
 tion  and to take  into  account the "...  impact of such final action
 on  production and prices  of  agricultural commodities, retail food
 prices, and otherwise  on  the agricultural economy. . . ."

                  Indemnifying for°all farmers'  losses in the event of
 an  emergency  suspension and  cancellation may be very expensive.
 Furthermore,  although  the loss is not entirely speculative, it would
 be  very difficult in  practice to  measure and verify it.  One could not
 predict transition costs, production  drops and the time needed for
 pesticide manufacturers to develop  and market a lower priced substi-
 tute.   Thus,  it might  be  possible to  make payments only some years
 after  the original pesticide cancellation when the costs were known.
 Even  then,  it would always be difficult to distinguish the production
 yield  decrease due to  other  factors,  such as weather, from the
 decrease due  solely to the different  pesticide.

                  Under these circumstances it might be more helpful to
 the farmers to prevent or limit the loss by providing for a more
 orderly transition period and stimulating the development of alter-
 native  pesticides.  By giving the industry some advance warning of the
 cancellation, allowing time  to Increase production of existing substi-
 tutes  and  accelerate the  development  of others, the losses are
 minimized.  This  is the procedure for ordinary, rather than emergency,
 cancellations —  the way  most pesticides are de-registered.

                  There was no problem of agricultural transition after
the Silvex  cancellations  because  only home and  garden uses were can-
 celled.   Because  some  other  uses  were not suspended,  and the emergency
 suspension  of the remainder  was challenged by registrants, cancella-
 tion has  not  gone into effect.  The anomaly of  the first major indem-
nification  case excluding farmers makes it difficult to base any
 conclusions concerning the operation  of § 15 on it*

            (b)   Banning  of  a Pesticide to Benefit the Public
                  Constitutes  a Taking of Property  for Which the
                  Government  Should  Pay Compensation

                  Some  asserted that the sudden  banning of a pesticide,
when accompanied  by the requirement that the pesticide be turned over
to EPA  for  disposal, constitutes  a  taking of property for which the
                                  -40-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 government should provide compensation.^2  A converse formulation of
 this  argument Is  that  the dereglstratlon of an unsafe pesticide con-
 fers  a benefit on the  public  that  should be paid for by the public.
 Important  to this argument is the  fact that § 15 *s compensation of all
 owners of  pesticides makes this  remedy very similar in form to compen-
 sation for a taking of property.

                  The problem  with  the taking argument is that the
 seizure of contraband  or  items  that  are  hazardous to public health
 does  not legally  qualify  for  compensation under the Fifth Amend-
 ment.-^ Nor is the government  legally estopped by its registration of
 the pesticide from asserting  that  the pesticide is unsafe.-"  By
 registering the pesticide,  the  government has clearly not stated that
 it believes the pesticide to  be  safe forever or that no evidence of
 potential  danger  will  be  found  in  the future.  Rather, the pesticide
 registration indicates only that,  at the time of the registration, the
 government did not have sufficient evidence to refuse registration.

             (c)   Indemnification is  needed to promote new pesticide
                  research and production

                  Arguments  were  strenuously made during the legisla-
 tive  debate on §  15 that,  without  financial protection from the possi-
 bility of  pesticide bans,  chemical companies would cease to undertake
 research and development  of new  pesticides.36  A less extreme argument
 was also made that substantial  financial losses due to pesticide can-
 cellations would  impede research and development.     In fact, however,
 no evidence has been found  either  that the availablity of Indemnifica-
 tion  stimulates new pesticide research and development or that pesti-
 cide  companies would reduce their  research and development efforts if
 indemnification were unavailable.  Rather, it appears that the manu-
 facturers  view the possibility of  dereglstration of any particular
 pesticide  as remote.   The  possibility that deregistration will involve
 a pesticide during the first  five  or ten years of  its useful life,
 before  It  "breaks  even" is  even  lower.   Thus, it does not seem to
 affect  research decisions.

                 The business of pesticides is so  volatile that the
manufacturers  must constantly innovate in order to stay in business.
 Its high profit margins indicate the risks of the  business, but also
provide  an  incentive to do  research  necessary to produce new products.
Furthermore,  the  indemnification under § 15 is only for the inventory
on hand  when a deregistration occurs.  It does not necessarily compen-
sate  the owner for the  cost of the putting the chemical on the market.

                 One analysis of the effect of paying for lost inven-
tory  on  a  pesticide's  net present  value  shows that such payments have
only  a small  impact compared  to the  effect of the  lost sales.
Paying Indemnification  for  lost inventory in the event of cancellation
increases  the  net  present value of a pesticide by  less than one
                                 -41-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 percent.This amount will probably not be sufficient to influence
 decision-making for most companies.  ^  Thus, loss of inventory is a
 crude  measure which not only fails to reflect a registrant's actual
 losses from a cancellation,  but  also may fail to provide the incen-
 tives  that Congress desired.

                  Other indemnification formula could be devised to
 have a greater impact on research.  One possibility would be to pay
 manufacturers for their total investment cost, less net revenue, with
 respect to a cancelled pesticide.   This formula is based on the fact
 that a relatively new chemical,  not  long on the market, would not yet
 have earned back its cost of research and development.   Promising to
 pay for investment cost less net revenues would at least guarantee the
 manufacturer that its research costs would not be lost.  This presum-
 ably would encourage manufacturers to continue to spend money to deve^
 lop new pesticides.

                  There would be  problems with this approach, however.
 If the chemical has been on  the  market for some time,  total sales will
 be greater than Investment.   A judgment would have to  be made whether
 the owner  should be compensated  for  the inventory under those circum-
 stances.   If the exclusive concern of indemnification  is with covering
 research and development costs,  then indemnities should not be paid
 for such inventory losses.  Furthermore, the cost of paying for devel-
 opment costs is likely to be much  higher than the cost  of inventory.
 Also,  it is difficult to Justify paying for research and development
 only for some cancellations  and  not  others.  Inventory  indemnification
 can be justified on the basis of the emergency suspension.

                  A much more direct  impact is exerted  by the expendi-
 tures  of the federal government  to support pesticide research and
 development.   The Department of  Agriculture and experiment  stations
 spent  $330 million in 1978,  approximately matching the  amount of pri-
 vate funds spent.   This federally  funded research even  results in
 industry-owned patents.^

             (d)  Indemnification encourages EPA to be more  careful
                  with its pesticide  registrations
                 A minor point  raised  during  the  §  15  debate  was  that
                 ificatlon  for deregistration  would  promi
ment to be more  careful with the original  registration.
requiring indemnification for deregistration would prompt  the govern-
                 The desired  feedback mechanism  probably cannot  work
because the registration process  is so  far  removed  from  possible
indemnification.  Of course the agency  would  not issue a registration
if It were contemplating revoking  it.   Deregistration and indemnifica-
tion occur many years  later.  More careful  application of statutory
pesticide registration requirements at  the  outset would  not  have pre-
vented the problems of new information  years  later.
                                 -42-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section  III
                 However,  there  is  some  evidence  that  the  current
 lengthy  review  process  already discourages  sone  potential  product
 manufacturers from  pursuing  the  registration  process,  even though,
 since  1972 EPA  has  actually  denied  registration  for  only  five  active
 ingredients.^

            (e)  Indemnification provides an  incentive to  comply with
                 deregistered pesticide  disposal  regulations

                 One Congressman argued  in  the §  15  debate that
 indemnification would increase compliance with EPA's regulations
 governing disposal  of cancelled  pesticides, because  owners would wish
 to comply with  these regulations in order to  collect their indem-
 nities.44

                 In order  for indemnification to  serve as  an effective
 incentive to assure proper disposal, pesticide owners  must know  that
 indemnification is  available.  While indemnity payments have been used
 as an  effective incentive  when the  federal  government  has  sought to
 destroy diseased livestock,  indemnification has not  actually been used
 by EPA in a similar way under §  15.  Indeed,  when EPA  sends out  stop-
 sale orders to  registrants and dealers of suspended  and potentially
 cancelled pesticides, no mention is made of the possible availability
 of indemnification.  Nevertheless,  pesticide  registrants may have
 viewed § 15 as an incentive  to agree to  cancellation of their  regis-
 trations, and the agreements signed with EPA  did  establish procedures
 for retrival and transfer  of Silvex to the  government  in addition to
 procedures for  filing indemnification claims.

                 Pesticide manufacturers are  generally large com-
 panies, well known  to the  government, and it  is relatively easy  to
 monitor their compliance with the deregistration.  Processors,
 dealers, and users  are much  more numerous,  small  and scattered.  Since
 the users are even  more difficult to Identify, it is difficult to
 notify them of cancellation.  Indemnification theoretically provides  a
more efficient means of passing  notice down the chain  of market  trans-
 actions.  A requirement that manufacturers  repurchase  stocks of  sus-
 pended and cancelled pesticides  would accomplish  some  of the same
 purposes achieved by indemnification.  The  third  parties who had
 relied on the continued use  of the  pesticide  would be  compensated.
They would have an  incentive, comparable to the present one, to  dis-
 pose of a dangerous substance properly.  However, what would be  lost
 in such a scheme would be  the motivation of the manufacturer to  do all
 that it can, rather than merely  what it must  do to achieve minimal
compliance with a repurchase requirement.   The substantial dependence
 of the Silvex disposal and claims processing  operation on  the  coopera-
 tion and good will  of the  registrant illustrates  the importance  of
maintaining their motivation for participation.
                                 -43-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
                  Indemnification makes it easier for EPA to decide in
                  favor of an emergency suspension because adverse
                  econon'i.c impacts will be partially covered by Indem-
                  nification

                  The idea behind this contention Is that EPA must con-
 sider  potential  adverse economic impacts when it Is making a suspen-
 sion decision, and indemnification might lessen those adverse economic
 impacts.

                  The problem with this argument is that it assumes a
 pool of available funds from which EPA can make indemnity payments.
 Such a pool  of funds does not exist.   The Court of Claims Judgment
 Fund might serve as such a pool, but  its availability to respond to
 repeated  § 15 claims is certainly open to question.  Moreover, con-
 sideration of indemnification in making suspension decisions appears
 to  be  contrary to the thinking of Congress because the Agency is
 directed  to  study and take into account only the economic impacts on
 the agricultural sector,  not on pesticide manufacturers.

        (2)  Arguments Against Indemnification

             (a)   Indemnification can  discourage suspension decisions
                  by EPA

                  This argument is based upon the idea that EPA may
 hesitate  to  ban  deadly and hazardous  pesticides if it knows that such
 a decision may cost the taxpayers millions of dollars, and especially
 if  indemnity funds must come from EPA's budget.

                  Although the specter of a "chilling effect" on EPA
 has been  raised  as a serious problem, the prospect of indemnification
 does not  appear  to have been an Important factor in previous suspen-
 sion and  cancellation decisions.  Rather, decisions have thus far been
 made on their scientific  and policy merits.  Clearly, however, the
 possibility  that EPA might have to reimburse the Court of Claims Judg-
 ment Fund for millions of dollars in  Silvex indemnification claims
 could  affect future suspension decisions.  Moreover, even if the
 prospect  of  having to pay Indemnification does not deter EPA from
 suspending and cancelling a pesticide,  the Agency might tend to reduce
 any margin of safety by permitting existing stocks of pesticides to be
 used or by allowing limited use of the  pesticide so as to avoid the
 need for  indemnification.

             (b)   Indemnification reduces industry incentives for
                  safety

                  During the legislative debate on § IS, the point was
made that indemnification would curb  incentives to the chemical
 industry  to  test their pesticides.^   Because the government pays for
                                 -44-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 losses  that  the  manufacturer  suffers  because  of  a §  15  pesticide  can-
 cellation, but pays  nothing for  stocks  produced  after  the  manufacturer
 has  knowledge disclosing  the  pesticide's  hazard,  § IS arguably dis-
 courages  any testing beyond what  is minimally necessary for  registra-
 tion.

                 There  is, as yet, no clear evidence concerning
 whether indemnification actually  reduces  industry safety activity.
 Nevertheless, the possibility of  indemnification theoretically provi-
 des  an  incentive to  pesticide registrants to  wait for government
 action, rather than  to  move voluntarily to withdraw  a pesticide from
 the  marketplace  and  thereby lose  the  opportunity for indemnities.

                 On  the other hand, there is  ample evidence  that  at
 least some pesticide manufacturers conduct safety research more exten-
 sive than is mandated by  EPA.  Often  a  manufacturer  and its  individual
 professional employees  will desire to conduct such research  in order
 to protect their business or  scientific reputations.

             (c)  Indemnification  for  pesticides  is unduly  preferen-
                 tial or  will prompt  a  flood  of  such indemnification
                 schemes

                 The contention here  is that  there is no reason to
 treat pesticide manufacturers differently from drug  manufacturers or
 other regulated parties that do not receive indemnification  if their
 products  are banned.^  An alternative  formulation of this argument
 Is that the  enactment of  pesticide indemnification sets a  precedent
 for  allowing indemnification of other dangerous  products that  are
 banned  from  the marketplace.

                 As  previously noted, there Is a long history  of  gov-
 ernment indemnities  to  farmers when their products have been destroyed
 or determined to be  dangerous to  health.   Pesticide  indemnification
 seems merely to continue  this history,  but only  a tiny  proportion of
 indemnities  actually paid under § IS  have gone to farmers.  (Probably
 no more than one or  two farmers have  been indemnified ever under
 § IS.)  Indemnification obviously benefits the pesticide manufacturers
 and  dealers, and gives  them an advantage  over drug manufacturers, for
 example,  who do not  receive indemnification if their products  lose  FDA
 approval.

                  Since the enactment of  § 15, there has been  no  flood
of new Indemnification  programs designed  to cover the losses of manu-
 facturers or dealers whose products prove to  be  dangerous  and  must  be
 removed from the marketplace.^  Thus,  there  Is  reason  to  believe
 that § 15 is not widely regarded  as a precedent  for  indemnification of
 such parties.
                                 -45-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
             (d)   For  reasons  of  economic  efficiency,  the risk of a
                  pesticide  ban should  be  borne by pesticide manufac-
                  turers  and sellers,  rather than by the government

                  This  argument makes  the  point that the possibility of
 cancellation based  on  new scientific  evidence of hazard is an ordinary
 business  risk which should  properly be internalized by the manufac-
 turer  or  seller  of  pesticides.   Indemnification instead allows produ-
 cers to gain the benefits and profits  of  the pesticide, while some of
 their  risk  is underwritten  by the  government.

                  Indeed, the  substantial  profit margins in the pesti-
 cide industry appear to  reflect  this  and  other risks.   The possibility
 of cancellation  Is  only  one of the risks  of the pesticide industry
 along  with  the risk of product liability,  the risk that insects will
 develop Immunities  to a  particular pesticide, and the  risk that a com-
 petitor will develop a superior  product.   All are routinely absorbed
 by the industry.  If the risk is reduced  by the government, the pesti-
 cide manufacturers  would enjoy a windfall  profit in the form of risk
 premiums  without  the risk,  not an  efficient allocation of resources.

    f.  Conclusion

        The  indemnification provision  has  not been used often enough
 to draw any  specific conclusions about its effect on the behavior of
 the agency or of  the pesticide industry.   In its present form, § 15
 operates  more like  individual payments made after a loss and after an
 arduous process  of  pursuing the claim  than like a more automatic pro-
 gram that can be  counted on before a loss  occurs.  If  it is desired
 that either  the  agency or the industry should take indemnification
 into account  in  their planning, some stable and reliable financing
 mechanism will have to be instituted.

        The  other conclusion that  can  be made is that  the presently
 constituted  indemnity section does not reach farmers,  who have
 received almost no payments so far.  Furthermore, inventory loss is
 not a  problem for them because, even if farmers were sent stop use
 orders, they  hold so little inventory,  that it would not be worth their
while  to  file  a complicated and lengthy procedure to obtain reimburse-
ment.  Their  real problem is with  the  disruption caused by losing the
 pesticide.   If present protections are judged to be Insufficient to
help them make a  transition, some  adjustment of the indemnification
provision would be necessary.

2.  Extension of FIFRA § 15 to New Situations

    a.   Application to TSCA

        The Toxic Substances Control Act is the first  place to con-
sider an extension of a FIFRA-like indemnification program.  The study
                                 -46-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 mandate grew out of a disagreement over whether there should be Indem-
 nification under TSCA.   There are also similarities in the laws that
 make  the question of extension to TSCA natural.  TSCA is the only
 other statute administered by EPA that significantly regulates partic-
 ular  products rather than processes or wastes.   EPA has the authority
 under both laws  to ban  a product, including the existing stocks.  An
 analysis of the  cost of a FIFRA-like indemnification program under
 TSCA  indicates that its cost  would be in the same range as that of
 FIFRA § 15.^° However, the transplant appears  to be unnecessary
 because there are significant differences both  in the statutes and in
 the substantive  area that each regulates.

         (1) Statutory Differences Between TSCA  and FIFRA

             TSCA is primarily an information development,  collection
 and coordination apparatus, rather than a comprehensive regulation of
 hazardous chemicals.^   it differs from FIFRA in many respects.  One
 Important difference is that  EPA does not register new chemicals under
 TSCA.   There is  a requirement that manufacturers give EPA  a 90 day
 notice  before beginning commercial production of a new chemical.
 However,  this is just a notification, and no test information need
 accompany the notice.   If the Agency finds reason to suspect a
 chemical,  it may order  the manufacturer to develop additional informa-
 tion  before beginning production.  Such orders, under § 5(e), have
 only  been issued on nine of the 1,450 chemicals reviewed since the
 program began.   (Of course, not even this limited review was available
 for the 50,000 chemicals introduced before TSCA's pre-market review
 was implemented.) There is no factual or legal  ground for  a company to
 rely  on the Agency's continued approval of any  chemical that passes
 through the preraanufacturing  notification review process.   The Act
 specifically provides for several kinds of follow-up regulation of new
 and existing chemicals  if new information, new  uses, or increased pro-
 duction volume signal reasons for concern.

             Another important difference between FIFRA and TSCA is the
 procedure  for emergency bans.  Under FIFRA,  emergency suspensions are
 Agency  orders.   They are reviewable by court on an expedited basis,
 but only  on grounds of  whether there is an imminent hazard and whether
 the suspension order was arbitrary or capricious.  In contrast,
 perhaps  in  an effort to prevent some of the  mistakes that  can result
 from emergency action,  Congress has given the decision to  an indepen-
 dent decision-maker.  Under TSCA,  If EPA wants  to take action against
 an existing chemical that is  causing an Imminent hazard, it must peti-
 tion a  federal district court for seizure or relief.  The  hearing pro-
vides an  opportunity for regulated parties to challenge the action and
 its factual and  legal basis.   The court may  order notification of
 purchasers,  recall,  repurchase,  or replacement.50

             A third important difference in  TSCA is the inclusion of
authority  to require  recalls  or repurchases.  If it were necessary to
                                 -47-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section  III
 remove  a  chemical  from  the  market,  some  kind  of  recall  or  repurchase
 scheme  probably would be  very  helpful.   The chemical  market  is  a  very
 •complex one,  and chemicals  are most  often  used as  intermediates in  the
 production  of other chemicals.  This sometimes happens  within one
 plant,  even within one  continuous and enclosed process.  Some chemi-
 cals  are  produced  as by-products of  others.   The large  volume chemi-
 cals  typically have many  uses, and  thus  many  types  of customers with
 different purposes.  It would  be difficult for a mandatory enforcement
 program to  ferret  out a chemical that follows a  convoluted path
 through the marketplace.  A repurchase scheme aids  in identifying and
 notifying the proper people by tracing them through market trans-
 actions.  The success of  Chevron in  obtaining an estimated 90t  of the
 Silvex  products held by its distributors and  retailers  is  due,  in
 part, to  the  organization of the voluntary repurchasing  effort, as
 well  as to  the prompt payment  of cash or credit  for the  goods.

            The comprehensive  authority  of TSCA, allowing  regulation
 of chemicals  from  manufacture  through processing and  use or  disposal,
 would allow a broad enough  repurchase order to avoid  the problems that
 occurred  in the Trie situation.^  The authority of TSCA can be used
 to spread the cost of any ban  among  all  of those involved  in manufac-
 ture  and  distribution, rather  than concentrating on those  who may not
 be able to  pay.

            But repurchase  requirements  alone might not  be enough to
 produce this  speedy and efficient result.  Conversely,  it  probably
 would not be  necessary to indemnify  for  the full cost of the inventory
 in order  to produce the necessary incentive.  (The  animal  disease
 program,  for  example, gets  good results  with  amounts  below the
 replacement value  of livestock because the rigorous enforcement also
 acts  as an  incentive.)

        (2) Alternatives  to Indemnification Under TSCA

            Section 2 of  TSCA declares that the  development  of  ade-
 quate data  on the  health  and environmental effects  should  be the
 responsibility of  the chemical manufacturers  and processors. Never-
 theless,  Congress  provided  many cost  limiting and cost  sharing  mea-
 sures;  illustrating the alternatives  to  indemnification  discussed in
Appendix  B.   For example, §  8 exempts small businesses  from  many  of
 the reporting and  recordkeeping requirements.  Section 9 contains ela-
borate  consultation procedures to prevent  conflicting or overlapping
 regulations of chemicals.   Nearly every  section  provides expanded
opportunities  for  participation and  comment before  agency  action
 (including  the emergency  action under §  7).   Section  6 mandates a
balance of  the risks of a chemical against the costs  of  various regu-
 latory  alternatives, and  requires the Administrator to  choose the
 least costly  alternative.   The cost  of testing existing  chemicals can
be shared among all the importers, manufacturers and  processors of
 the chemical.
                                 -48-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
         (3)  Impeding Statutory Incentives for Self-Regulation

             The  existence  of TSCA,  even in advance of full implementa-
 tion,  has  encouraged ami  supported  various voluntary and private
 efforts  to reduce  the risk of chemicals to health and the environment.
 There  is evidence  that many chemical manufacturers do test new
 chemicals,  even  though the premanufacturing notice does not require
 any  tests.   A successful  effort is  being made to negotiate with the
 manufacturers of chemicals listed by the Interagency Test Committee to
 arrange  voluntary  testing  of existing chemicals, without promulgation
 of a formal  test rule. Some companies are reporting the voluntary
 remedial measures  taken in response to problems reported to the Agency
 under  §  8(e). There are  advantages for both the chemical Industry and
 the  Agency in making such  arrangements.  The chemical companies have
 more control over  their response to the chemical risk, and in some
 cases  are  able to  restrict the amount of confidential Information
 given  to the Agency.  The  industry  does not have to spend as much time
 and  money  commenting on regulations.  Advantages to the Agency to
 include  decreased  cost, speedier results, and increased cooperation of
 the  regulated industry.

             This delicate  web of agreements, arrangements, and incen-
 tives  could  be disrupted by the counter-incentive of an indemnifica-
 tion program. The possibility of more costly compliance with
 regulations  and  of possible adverse publicity is presently an incen-
 tive for the companies to  detect and begin to correct problems with
 their  products.  Although  indemnification for inventory would not
 fully  compensate a manufacturer for the loss associated with a ban, it
would  be an  Incentive to wait for the Agency to take action rather
 than to  respond  immediately to the  perceived problem.  The impact of
an indemnification program is hard  to gauge, but its direction may run
counter  to the incentives  in the statute and the present method of its
 implementation.

         (A)  Frequency of Bans Under TSCA

             One  of the primary reasons for setting up an indemnifica-
tion program is  to handle  a large volume of indemnification payments.
There  are  several  differences between the chemicals regulated under
TSCA and those regulated under FIFRA which may lead to fewer emergency
bans under TSCA.   Pesticides are designed to be dangerous to certain
forms  of life; they are called "economic poisons."  The average chemi-
cal  under  the broad jurisdication of TSCA is not harmful either to
human  health or  the environment. Whereas non-pesticide chemicals have
a multitude  of uses and vast differences in the exposure to people,
most pesticides  are used on the food chain.  Anything in the food
chain  has a  measurable, if attenuated,  exposure link to people.  In
addition,  the exposure to  the environment is much greater with pesti-
cides  since  they are used  in fields, forests, along roads and in
homes.
                                 -49-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
             In contrast, most industrial chemicals are converted
 within a factory into a stable end-use product.  Thus, the exposure is
 generally only to workers within the factory, and not to the customers
 or the general environment.  The considerations of toxicity and expo-
 sure are the important ones in determining whether and how quickly to
 regulate.  The lower average toxicity and exposure of industrial chem-
 icals indicates less frequent need for emergency bans.

             Even when a chemical does need to be regulated under TSCA,
 it is more likely to be a regulation of some uses, rather than a total
"ban on all uses.  Industrial chemicals often have a wide variety of
 uses.  Some of them may cause much more exposure or may be more harm-
 ful than others.  Section 6 requires the Administrator to regulate by
 using the least burdensome means that will adequately protect against
 the risk.  Thus, it is likely that the Administrator would regulate
 some uses and not others, leaving a continued market for the chemical.
 This was true, for example, of the only ban to date, that of CFC
 aerosals.  Many other uses of CFC's, in refrigeration, air condition-
 ing, sterilization, and plastic formation have not been regulated at
 all.  Aerosals were considered to cause the most Immediate threat to
 the ozone layer, and to be the least necessary to the economy.

         (5) Equitable Basis for Indemnification Under TSCA

             Many operational errors possible under TSCA would be the
 basis for a cause of action under the FTCA.  A mistake like the one in
 the Mlzokaml Brothers case, that could not be the basis for a FTCA
 suit, seems unlikely to occur under TSCA.  The chances for error are
 reduced by the fact that the Agency does not itself test chemicals, as
 the FDA does food.   Furthermore, EPA cannot seize a chemical without a
 hearing.  If there  had been a hearing before the seizure in the
 Mizokami case, it seems likely that the hearing officer would have at
 least stayed the order until another test could been conducted.  Most
 of the Mizokami's loss was spinach that would not keep for six weeks
 while the parties argued over it.  Chemicals on the other hand, prob-
 ably could survive  a dispute without loss of intrinsic value (although
 there might be associated losses such as lost business opportunities).

             It is also unlikely that there will be a problem like the
 FDA announcement that eliminated the market for cranberries in 1959
 because it did not  distinguish between contaminated cranberries and
 untainted ones.  The strength of the public reaction to that announce-
 ment apparently took everyone by surprise.  Both Congress and the
 agencies are now more careful in assigning and using the power of pub-
 licity.  EPA may only add the name of a chemical which it suspects may
 present an unreasonable risk to TSCA's "risk list," § 5(b)(4), after a
 procedure more elaborate than that required for most rulemakings.

             There is one instance in which Congress has considered
 indemnification for consequences of a potential action under TSCA.  In
                                   -50-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 1980,  Congress  authorized  a  grant  program to  cover  the  costs  of
 detecting  and correcting problems  of  asbestos  insulation  in  school
 buildings.   The aid  was for  school districts  that had  to  correct  an
 environmental problem  they had  not created.   The  legislation  was
 passed before EPA  had  proposed  rules  requiring inspection of  schools,
 but  the funding has  never  been  provided.   In  the  meantime, many  states
 have established their own grant programs, or  some  other  form of
 assistance  for  the school  districts.

         (6)  Conclusion on  TSCA

             There  appears  to  be no reason to  transfer  an  indemnity
 program like that  in FIFRA §  15 to TSCA.   There is  no  evidence of the
 kind of losses  envisioned  by  the drafters of  § 15 due  in  part to  the
 differences  between  the statutes and  their subject  matter. TSCA  con-
 tains  many  other methods of preventing, limiting, and  sharing the
 costs  of regulation, and it does not  appear that  there  will be fre-
 quent  or complete  bans.  Experience in  implementing TSCA  is limited,
 but  so far  there are no patterns of inequities that would justify
 establishment of an  indemnification program.

    b.   Product Recalls

         (1)  Description

             The other  logical extension of §  15 is  to  product recalls.
 However, there  are very few such recalls  in the EPA-administered
 statutes.  As mentioned, TSCA contains  recall  authority,  but  it has
 not yet  been used.  The only  significant  recall provision that has
 been used by EPA is  that in § 207(c)  of the Clean Air Act.

             Automobiles may be  recalled for adjustment  if they do not
 meet the applicable  emission  limitations  throughout their useful  life,
 when properly maintained.  The  recall may occur up  to  five years  or
 50,000 miles after their initial sale.  Of the 223  recalls since  1973,
 163 have been voluntarily  undertaken, without  any action  by EPA,  when
 the manufacturer discovered a defect.  EPA has issued  formal  recall
 orders  only  21  times,  two  of  them  contested.   The remainder were
 "influenced  recalls,"  in which  EPA discovered  a problem and began
working  on a recall order, but  the  manufacturer voluntarily recalled
before  it was issued.

            The cost per car of recall and repairs  has  been $15-20 on
average.  However, recalls may  apply  to millions of cars,  and the
 total  cost to the  manufacturer  can be quite large.   It  is estimated
 that about 50%  of  the  cars in the  categories  that are recalled are
actually brought in  for repair.  One  reason for indemnification in
 this situation  might be to increase the participation rate.   The
 situation is a  classic one in which the cost"(or annoyance to the
owner)  is not balanced by  a benefit to the individual.  The benefits
                                 -51-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
are  derived  only  from  Che  participation  of  a significant  number  of
others.   It  is  possible  that,  if  the  manufacturers  were  indemnified
for  their costs,  they  would  change  their approach to  notification or
otherwise make  a  greater effort to  increase participation.

        (2)  Evaluation

             There does not appear to  be  a high  probability  of  surprise
or agency error in  the recall  of  automobiles.   The  automobile  manufac-
turers are notified whenever EPA  test their cars,  and are invited to
attend as observers.   Thus,  they  are  aware  of the data on which  EPA
would base a recall from the beginning.   Frequently they  conduct inde-
pendent tests to  confirm it.  The statistics suggest  that EPA  Is
usually correct, because the automobile  makers  often  take voluntary
action at considerable expense, rather than waiting for EPA to order
it.  When an order  is  contested,  It can  be  stayed pending the  outcome
of the suit.  Therefore, the manufacturer does  not  have to  incur the
expense of complying with  what might  be  a mistaken  order, unlike the
case of emergency action to  curtail production  during the Birmingham
air pollution alert.5^

             It  is not  clear, of course,  that indemnifying the  manufac-
turer will,  in  fact, increase  participation by  car  owners.   There is
no out-of-pocket cost  to the owner  in a  recall,  just  the  inconvenience
of being  without a  car.  The indemnification cannot change  the fact
that there is no  individual  benefit to the  owner.   Unless the  repair
of the emissions system  makes  the car run better or more  efficiently,
the incentive to the individual Is only  that he  is  contributing  to the
public health.  An alternative way  to increase  participation would be
institution  of mandatory inspection and  maintenance programs.  The
threat of  failing inspection may  be a better incentive for  all owners.

        (3)  Conclusion on Recalls

             Indemnification  does  not  appear to  be an  appropriate
adjunct to the automobile  recall  program.   Recalls  are generally not
emergencies.  There is ample notice,  opportunity to inspect data and
confirm it,  and to contest the order'before compliance*   The procedure
also reduces the possibility of error on the part of  the  Agency.
Indemnification would  probably not be an effective  incentive to
increase  the participation of  automobile owners.
                                 -52-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section  IIL



    C.   INDEMNIFICATION UNDER § 202(a)(3) OF THE CLEAN  WATER ACT

1.  The  Existing Program

    a.   Introduction

         Indemnification under § 202(a)(3) of the Clean  Water Act  of
1977,"  as amended in 1981,^ was designed,  in  part,  as an  incentive
to encourage the development of innovative and  alternative  wastewater
treatment technologies."  The provision was originally drafted in
Conference in 1977 to supplement the incentives created by  § 202(a)(2),
which provides federal grant money for up to 85% of  the cost of treat-
ment plants, or unit process and techniques  thereof,  that employ  inno-
vative or alternative technology, rather than the 75% (or up to 55%
beginning in FY 1985) normally provided.56   Congressional debate  on
§ 202(a)(3) characterized it as an "Insurance policy" covering the
risk of  failure of such technology.^

        Under § 202(a)(3), EPA is given discretion to fund  100% of the
costs of modification or replacement of an innovative or alternative
facility that fails to meet performance specifications  and  has signi-
ficantly increased capital, operating or maintenance  expenditures.  An
additional statutory prerequisite is that the plant  failure  not be
attributable to negligence.  EPA's May 1982  interim  final rule under
the section also requires that the failure occur within a two-year
period following Initial operation of the project. °

        Section 202(a)(3) has only been utilized in  one or  two instan-
ces to provide replacement or modification funds for  treatment works
failure.59  However, it has been used to encourage grantees  to use
innovative or alternative technology.

    b.  Statutory Language and Regulations

        Section 202(a)(3) of the Clean Water Act of  1977, 33  U.S.C.
§ 1282(a)(3), provides:

              "(3) In addition to any grant made pursuant to
         paragraph (2) of this subsection, the  Administrator
         is authorized to make a grant to fund  all of the
         costs of the modification or replacement of any
         facilities constructed with a grant made pursuant
         to paragraph (2) if the Administrator  finds  that
         such facilities have not met design performance
         specifications unless such failure  is  attributable
         to negligence on the part of any person and  if such
         failure has significantly Increased capital or
         operating and maintenance expenditures.
                                 -53-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
         Regulatory  implementation of §  202(a)(3) is codified  at 40
 C.F.R.  § 35.2032(c),  which  provides:

               (c)   Modification  or replacement of innovative
          and  alternative  projects.  The Regional Administra-
          tor  may award  grant  asistance  to fund 100 percent
          of the allowable costs  of the  modification or
          replacement  of any project funded with increased
          grant funding  in accordance with paragraph (a)  of
          this section if  he determines  that:

               (1)   The  innovative or alternative elements of
          the  project  have caused the project  or significant
          elements of  the  complete waste treatment system of
          which the  project  is part to fail to meet project
          performance  standards;

               (2)   The  failure has significantly increased
          operation  and  maintenance expenditures for the  pro-
          ject or the  complete waste treatment system of
          which the  project  is part;  or  requires significant
          additional capital expenditures for  corrective
          action;

               (3)   The  failure has occurred prior to two
          years after  Initiation  of operation  of the project;
          and

               (4)   The  failure is not attributable to negli-
          gence on the part  of any person.

    c.   Legislative History of § 202(a)(3)

         Section 202(a)(3) did not appear in either the original House
or Senate versions  of the 1977 Water  Act,  but was added  later in
Conference.60 The  subsequent House debate on the Conference  Report
characterized the provision as an "insurance  policy" designed to cover
the risks created by  forcing  technology and to provide an incentive
for the  use of innovative or  alternative technology in wastewater
treatment works.^  It  was  enacted in order to facilitate achievement
of the benefits of  the  new  technology,  despite higher risks associated
with it.

         Congress in 1977 wanted  to strengthen its encouragement of
Innovative and alternative  wastewater treatment systems  by adding
financial incentives.^2   It was  the  sense  of  the Congress that there
had been insufficient progress in response to the encouraging language
of the 1972 Act.  Apparently,  the Conference  Committee felt that it
was also  necessary  to reinforce  and  supplement the incentive  provided
by the 10% additional federal grant money  provided under § 202(a)(2).63

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 In  enacting § 202(a)(2)  and  §  202(a)(3),  Congress clearly intended
 that  local governments be permitted and encouraged to use wastewater
 treatment  technology Involving higher risks of potential failure.

    d.   Implementation of §  202(a)(3)

         (1) Regulations  and  Guidance Documents

             As quoted above, an interim final rule implementing
 § 202(a)(3) was published May  12,  198264  as part of the new regula-
 tions made necessary by  the  December 29,  1981 enactment of the
 Municipal  Wastewater Treatment Construction Grant Amendments of
 1981."  xhe previous regulations  were published on September 27,
 1978.66  The new (1982)  interim rule provisions dealing with modifica-
 tion  and replacement costs are essentially  the same as the 1978
 regulations,  although the language has been changed for reasons of
 clarity  and to conform with  related changes in the grants program.

             A May 1982 draft Guidance Document entitled "Construction
 Grants - 1982" contains  procedures for awarding 100% modification  or
 replacement grants.   This document establishes the criteria for the
 exercise of EPA's discretion in funding replacement or modification
 costs.   The overall  document generally emphasizes an "ongoing effort
 to  simplify and delegate the municipal construction grants program."

             Section  15.2 at  110 states that:

                   The key to  implementation of I&A
               [Innovative & Alternative]  projects Is the
               acceptance of an acceptable level of risk by
               you that the I or A  project may not work as
               predictably as a more  conventional treatment
               process.

                   For the purpose of  100 percent M/R
               [Modification/Replacement]  funding,  failure is
               defined  as the Inability of the entire system
               or  significant components to  meet design per-
               formance specifications, where  such failure is
               due  to higher risk elements of  design as
               determined in the  original  design documents.
              M/R  100  percent  funding  is  not  available where
               the  failure  of an  I  or A system or component
               is  covered by a  warranty or caused by
              negligence.

            The Guidance Document  further explains that evaluation of
requests for  100Z modification or  replacement grants will involve  a
determination  that:

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
               (a)  design  performance  specifications have not
               been met; (b)  the  failure  results  in a signi-
               ficant  increase  in O&M  [Operation  & Mainten-
               ance] costs  and/or requires  additional
               significant  capital expenditures  to correct
               the  problem; and (c)  the failure  is not attri-
               butable to  negligence on the part  of any
               person.  Negligence should be evaluated as the
               last item since  the determination  is based
               upon both technical analysis and  legal
               findings.

                   Initial  screening will reject  from further
               consideration  projects  which do not qualify
               for  obvious  reasons and, therefore, do not
               require a detailed evaluation.  Such reasons
               may  include  expiration  of  the two-year period,
               hydraulic or organic  overloading of the system
               or lack of  an  adequate  O&M program.

        (2) Potential  Utilization

            Section 202(a)(3)  has only been in effect long enough to
result in one  or two  limited instances of  replacement or modification
costs for any  failed  innovative  or  alternative systems.

            The total  facility cost for  projects funded  under
§ 202(a)(2) through September  30,  1981 is  approximately  $1 to  $1.5
billion.  This includes approximately 250  grant  awards for innovative
technology and 1000 for alternative technology.^  Because EPA
believes that  § 202(a)(3) funds  should be  used to cover  the risk  of
failures in unproven  technology,  it plans  to  focus on innovative  uses
of waste water technologies.

            Thus,  EPA's exposure  for  total replacement of innovative
technology funded  through September 30,  1981  may be between $200-$375
million, if replacement costs  equal the  corresponding initial  expendi-
tures.  Of course, such exposure  would require failure of all  of  the
innovative facilities, as well as complete replacement at an amount
equal to the original  costs.   It  would also require that all of  the
failures occur within  two years  of  the date of final inspection.
Therefore, actual  funding needs  are likely to be far less than the
maximum exposure of $375 million  for  these projects.  If they  are as
high as 10% of this amount,  total indemnification costs  would  be  on
the order of one percent of  the  total FY 1980 Construction Grants
               Aft
appropriation.00
                                 -56-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
             With the 1981 legislation,  Congress made the innovative/
 alternative program a continuing part of the Construction Grants
 program.69   EPA's exposure for replacement or modification will there-
 fore also continue*

     e.   Benefits and Problems of § 202(a)(3)

        Although § 202(a)(3)  was designed to assure the correction of
 a  malfunctioning Innovative or alternative wastewater treatment system,
 the  provision also was enacted to stimulate the use of innovative or
 alternative technology.   However, its practical effectiveness as an
 Incentive is diminished  by the lack of  a specific funding reserve to
 assure  the  availability  of money when it is needed.

        Because  of the lack of specific funding, the prospect of
 indemnification  has been viewed with some skepticism by grantees.  For
 most grantees who have decided to utilize Innovative or alternative
 technology, the  primary  motivating factor seems to have been the
 availability of  the 10Z  higher grant assistance under § 202(a)(2).70
 This incentive,  however,  provides a stimulus for somewhat different
 conduct  than is  promoted by § 202(a)(3).  Section 202(a)(2) encourages
 grantees  to adopt the minimum level of  innovative and alternative
 technology  that  will qualify  for the extra grant assistance.  Section
 202(a)(3),  in contrast,  Is supposed to  encourage true risk-taking by
 indemnifying against the risk of technological failure of innovative
 and  alternative  treatment works.  The former incentive has outweighed
 and  probably negated the second.

        There also is the problem that  a potential indemnltee under
 §  202(a)(3) must compete for  funding priority with other potential
 grantees.   In addition,  payment of indemnification is entirely discre-
 tionary under the Act, which  is thus vastly different from a legally
 binding commercial insurance  policy with specific reserves and
 detailed  criteria for payment.

     f.  Problems with §  202(a)(3) That  Might be Remedied

        As  with  §  15 of  FIFRA,  a possible deficiency with § 202(a)(3)
 is the absence of guaranteed  funding.   While a general funding mecha-
nism exists,  and replacement  and modification grants are authorized to
be paid out  of overall grant  funds for  construction of treatment works,
no money has  actually been set  aside to cover the contingency of a
 facility  failure.   In other words,  there is no assurance that the
grant program itself or  any necessary funding under it will actually
exist when  failure occurs.  Further,  a  grant application for replace-
ment or modification funding  will have  to compete on the priority list
against grant  applications for  original construction.   Thus,  rather
 than being  an insurance  policy  that  guarantees funding,  § 202(a)(3)
merely establishes eligibility  if funding is available.
                                 -57-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
         One way to correct this would be to set aside specific money
 In a government trust fund reserve,  similar to a commercial insurance
 reserve,  with use limited  to replacement or modification funding.  An
 alternative would be to use a portion of the grant money set aside for
 innovative technology to purchase a  commercial insurance policy
 covering  the risk of system failure.  Either of these approaches would
 provide  a greater incentive for use  of innovative technology since
 potential grantees would be more assured of protection from the risk
 of failure due to the use  of a new and unproven technology*

        A second  issue is  that EPA has placed a two-year limitation on
 the  time  period during which an idemnifiable failure must occur.  EPA
 concluded that a  two-year  period would provide ample operational
 experience with the treatment works, so that a failure due to the use
 of innovative technology would very  likely occur, if at all, during
 this period.  Nevertheless, certain  types of failures might not become
 evident until after the two-year period — for example, unrealized
 life-cycle cost savings — and some  type of allowance might be made
 for  this  contingency.   Comments on EPA's regulation before it was
 promulgated indicated  substantial support for longer time periods —
 as long as ten years — but this is  not the only possible modification
 to alleviate this alleged  problem.

     g.  Summary Evaluation of the Existing Program

        Section 202(a)(3)  is an example of the use of indemnification
 to support a government policy objective.  This provision represents a
 type of indemnification somewhat similiar to private contractual
 indemnification.

        Even though §  202(a)(3) has  only had very limited application
 to pay indemnification for a failed  innovative facility,  it has been
 offered as an incentive to stimulate the use of new technology.
 However,  Its value as  an incentive has been limited by the lack of
 guaranteed funding,  and by the more  important and partially counter-
 vailing incentive of innovative technology construction grants under
 §  202(a)(2).

 2.   Possible Modifications of the Existing Program

     a.  Expansion of Eligible Costs

        The  Municipal  Wastewater Treatment Construction Grant Amend-
ments of  1981^1 increased  the number of technology innovations poten-
 tially eligible for  funding under §  203(a)(2),  and for "insurance"
under § 202(a)(3), by  making innovative or alternative unit processes
and  techniques  eligible for the first  time.   Under the amendments, it
Is no longer necessary for innovative  technology to comprise a sub-
stantial  portion  of  the treatment works to be eligible for the indem-
nification of § 202(a)(3).
                                 -58-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
         Further expansion of §  202 along these lines, however, now
 seems unworkable.   Virtually all innovation is now covered within
 the program,  and any further additions,  therefore, would necessarily
 involve technology that is not  innovative or alternative.  While an
 argument could be  made that all failures of wastewater treatment tech-
 nology cause  losses worthy of EPA reimbursement, the principal ratio-
 nale for §  202(a)(3) remains the creation of an incentive to take the
 special risk  of innovative or alternative technology.  That incentive
 would be undermined if similar  indemnification were available for
 treatment works, processes or techniques that are not innovative or
 alternative.

     b.   Expansion  of Eligible Grant Recipients

         In  addition to its construction  grants program, EPA has also
 conducted a much smaller  demonstration grants program under §§ 104 and
 105 of the  Clean Water Act.'2  The grantees under this program were
 both municipal treatment  works  and parties seeking to demonstrate par-
 ticular pollution-control technology which thereafter could be mar-
 keted to industrial sources. The function of the demonstration grants
 from their  perspective was to reduce the costs of demonstrating a par-
 ticular technology where  these  costs might otherwise interfere with
 the technology's ever reaching  the market.  From EPA's perspective,
 the function  of demonstration grants was analogous to the function of
 §  202 grants:   to  promote innovation in  water pollution control.
 Approximately $20-30 million was budgeted during 1967-70 for indus-
 trial demonstration projects and a similar amount for municipal demon-
 stration projects.'-*  However,  the relatively low level of municipal
 participation in the demonstrations ultimately led to the enactment of
 §  202(a)(2),  and § 104 funding  for municipal demonstrations was cur-
 tailed  thereafter.

         The industrial demonstration grant program,  as a practical
 matter,  is  limited to technological innovations that cannot possibly
 be  utilized on a publicly-owned facility because, if such utilization
Is  possible,  § 202(a)(2)  provides more favorable terms to the control
 device  manufacturer.   Since some publicly-owned facilities in fact
 treat  a single finns's wastes almost inclusively, the opportunity may
 exist  for industrial  pollution  control technologies  to be demonstrated
 as  innovative  technology  under  § 202(a)(2).   Thus, the scope of the
 demonstration  grants  program Is  limited  by definition.  Moreover, Its
 practical scope  is  further limited by the virtual termination of
 funding  In recent  years.^

         The possibility that the offer of Indemnification might pro-
 duce  a  practical incentive effect on technology innovation under the
 demonstration  grants  program is  thus quite small.  It is reduced fur-
 ther  by  the fact that  it  is not  the risk of  failures that seems to
 inhibit  pollution  control  demonstrations, but rather the cost of the
 demonstrations  themselves.   Thus,  in most instances, the barrier to
                                 -59-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Section  III
 final  marketing  of  the  technology  is  effectively  removed  if  the  grant
 is  made,  and  no  further incentive  for  the  manufacturer  is  needed.   The
 industrial  source  similarly  appears  to  have  no  special  disincentive to
 participate  because  of  the  risk  of  failure since,  In  most  circum-
 stances,  it  is merely providing  an  effluent  stream  to be  cleaned.   At
 most,  If  the  risk  of failure  proves  to  be  a  special disincentive in a
 peculiar  circumstance,  some  individual  remedial measure — such  as  a
 special insurance  policy — might be  called  for.  In  fact, however,
 there  have apparently never been any  instances  where  indemnification
 was  sought, or Insurance against failure  thought  to be  needed, under
 the  clean water  demonstration grants  program. ->

 3.   Possible  Applications of  the §  202(a)(3) Model  In Other  EPA
     Programs

     a.  Introduction

        The Clean Water Act's innovative and alternative  technology
 program in §  202 integrates a construction grants program  with an
 indemnification  provision applicable  to publicly-owned  wastewater
 treatment facilities.   It defines desired  behavior, not otherwise
 required  to meet EPA18  regulatory requirements  (innovative and alter-
 native technology).  That behavior  involves a risk  that may  deter some
 parties who would otherwise consider  undertaking  the  behavior (risk of
 plant  failure).  If  harm actually occurs,  the indemnification program
 offers reimbursement for some of the  damages incurred (the costs of
 retrofitting  or  replacing the wastewater treatment  plant —  but  not
 the  damages from pollution caused by  the failed plant). Thus, the
 incentive is  created by the promise of  reimbursement  (sometimes  made a
 specific  "selling point" in negotiations over construction grants).

     b.  Candidate Indemnification Measures

        (1) Clean Air Act

            A fundamental difference  exists between the Clean Water
Act's § 202 incentive and the various innovative  and  alternative
 incentives under the Clean Air Act:   there is no  substantial govern-
ment funding  of  the  cost of compliance with  the Clean Air  Act.
Rather, in virtually all instances, the Clean Air Act contemplates
 that the  economic burden of the  air program should  be borne  by regu-
 lated parties.  This policy does not  preclude reliance  on  Indemnifica-
tion incentives  to foster desired behavior, but such  Incentives  are
 logically more defensible where  the judgment has  been made to share at
 least some compliance costs.

            In contrast to §  202 of the Clean Water Act, a primary
 incentive to  use innovative and  alternative technology  to  comply with
Clean Air Act requirements is the possibility of  obtaining a limited
waiver of applicable emission limitations  under § lll(J)  (sources sub-
                                 -60-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 ject to New Source Performance Standards)  and § 113(d)  (existing
 sources subject  to state  implementation plan requirements).   Such
 waivers eliminate  some  of the risk a source incurs by utilizing inno-
 vative  rather  than conventional technology, since the principal harms
 that result from Che  failure of such technology are pollution (the
 effects of  which are  largely external to the source and arguably sanc-
 tioned  by the  waiver) and regulatory violation costs (which  are
 waived).  Thus,  the need  for an indemnification incentive Is not
 established.

            Another mechanism, however, is somewhat more analogous to
 §  202.   Under  the  Clean Air  Act,  EPA uses  demonstration grants to
 stimulate innovative  pollution control technology.76  Typically, these
 demonstration  projects  are cost-shared, with the government  picking up
 as  much as  half  the cost, and the rest being financed by private
 parties, such  as a vendor of a new control device whose demonstration
 costs are prohibitive without EPA's assistance.77  However,  unlike the
 innovative  and alternative technology program under the Clean Water
 Act, and like  the  Clean Water Act Industrial demonstration grants
 program, many  of the  ideas for demonstration funding come from such
 private parties.   This  differs from the "classic" incentive  indem-
 nification  model,  since EPA  does  not need  to recruit private party's
 participation  in the demonstration.   On the other hand, EPA  does
 instigate some demonstration projects on its own.  Nevertheless,
 because funds  for  demonstrations  depend on the existence of  a tech-
 nology  to be demonstrated, the program depends more on  Initiatives
 outside EPA than does the §  202 program.

            The  potential benefits  to vendors of a successful demon-
 stration are clear.  Thus, reduction of the cost of the demonstration,
 by  means of an EPA grant,  may be  a  sufficient Incentive for  such
 parties, especially if  they  can proceed without fear of liability.  On
 the  other hand,  host sources may  be  less inclined to participate.  To
 be  sure, some of these  sources may  wish to help solve a current or
 potential pollution control  problem,  such  as finding a  more  cost-
 effective method of control,  a method by which a future emission limi-
 tation  can  be achieved  or an appropriate control method for  future
 facilities.  This  is quite different,  however,  from the public reci-
 pients  of § 202  funds,  for which  compliance with EPA standards without
 EPA grant money  is  a practical impossibility.

            The  risks of  participation are similar for  the demonstra-
 tion grants program as  for §  202(a)(3).  A demonstration of  equipment
 that fails will  often require  that  the equipment be replaced or con-
verted  to its original  or  some other configuration.  Another potential
risk of failure  is  that the  demonstration  technology may interfere
with the production processes  of  the emission source.   Both  of these
types of harms Involve  costs  that are  normally not a part of the ori-
ginal grant.  On the other hand,  they  may  be similar to other business
risks,  commonly  absorbed  by  industry but quite impossible for public
 facility owners  to  accommodate.
                                 -61-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
             In  theory,  these types of risks can be remedied through
 the  use  of  Indemnification and,  In at least one demonstration grant
 circumstance,  the  need  for Indemnification was actually perceived.   In
 an EPA demonstration  contract with Combustion Engineering Involving a
 demonstration  project at  Utah Power & Light Co.,  indemnification was
 regarded  as  essential by  the host  source before it would agree to par-
 ticipate  in  a  project involving  the alteration of boiler combustion
 with  a new  type  of burner and related equipment.'"  In particular,  the
 host  source  required  indemnification against any damage to the boiler
 or loss of  production due to the project.  EPA did not agree to Indem-
 nify  the  host  source  directly, however,  since it  chose instead to
 include approximately $500,000 of  contract funds  for a privately-
 placed insurance policy to cover potential losses.79

        (2)  RCRA

             Under  RCRA, an analogy to the objectives of Innovative,
 alternative  or demonstration programs can be articulated, and the pos-
 sible utilization  of  an indemnification  incentive is thus suggested.
 Hazardous waste  technology does  Involve  risks, and those risks argu-
 ably  contribute  to the  barrier to  hazardous waste technology implemen-
 tation.  To  the  extent  that they do,  indemnification could plausibly
 be used to  stimulate  wider implementation.  Such  indemnification could
 not presently be attached to a grant  from EPA, since no such grants
 are presently made.   However,  the  lack of an existing administrative
 mechanism for effecting indemnification  would not necessarily preclude
 the adoption of a  new mechanism  to achieve that purpose.

    c.  Rationale  for Indemnification

        Indemnification for failed innovative technology does not
 directly  stimulate the  use or  testing of such technology.  Instead, it
 serves to remove certain  disincentives,  such as the risk of potential
 failure of the innovative technology,  the risk that the source's
 equipment will in  some  way be damaged, and the risk of environmental
 impairment.  Thus,  indemnification can function only to complement
 whatever primary incentives support the  use of Innovative technology.
 These incentives may  be the prospect  of  commercial rewards to a manu-
 facturer of  a successfully tested new pollution  control technology,
 the anticipated benefits  to a source  in  meeting regulatory require-
ments, or the potential for a higher  level of government grant funding
 than would be available for conventional technology.  In other words,
 In order  for indemnification to  operate  in this context there must  be
an underlying commercial,  regulatory,  or government funding incentive
which supports the use  of Innovative  technology in the first place.

        The  Clean  Air Act demonstration  project program offers a
potential context  for the use of indemnification, closely analogous to
 § 202(a)(3).  The  program involves activity which EPA desires to
encourage in support  of its Clean  Air  Act objectives (demonstration of
                                 -62-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 new technology).   That  activity  may  involve  a  risk that  makes  it
 uneconomical  to  the  party  who  would  otherwise  engage in  it  (equipment
 failure,  production  interruption,  environmental  impairment  liability).
 If  that  risk  were  to result  in harm,  significant costs might  be
 imposed  (for  retrofit or replacement,  for  lost production or  for  the
 payment  of  damages). Thus,  the  promise  of indemnification  provides an
 incentive for participation  (for example,  by contractural arrange-
 ment) .

         The analogy  to  RCRA  is less  precise.   EPA has  not yet  adopted
 a policy of directly fostering Improved  hazardous waste  technology
 implementation, although the policy  may  be implied as  operating stan-
 dards  for treatment,  storage and disposal  are  developed.  Hazardous
 waste  technology does Involve  risk,  but  the  technology EPA  may wish to
 promote  would probably  involve fever environmental risks  than  conven-
 tional technology, while the more  important  barrier to its  implemen-
 tation is its higher cost  and  the  comparatively  low demand  for it.
 Nevertheless,  if the technology  proves faulty, the losses that result
 may be substantial and, for  this reason, a promise of  indemnification
 might  provide some incentive for implementation  of the technology.

    d.   Evaluation of Indemnification

        The desirability of  Incentive indemnification  must  be  eval-
 uated  in  each distinct  context where it  is proposed.   In  each  context,
 a threshold question Is whether  this type of indemnification is viable
 without  a corresponding government funding program similar  to
 § 202(a)(2).   That question can  be answered  affirmatively,  only if
 government  policy  to encourage use of innovative  technology is sup-
 ported by a willingness to fund  modification or  replacement costs  if
 necessary.

         In  contexts  where  there  is such  support,  the next question is
 the choice  between indemnification and commercial insurance covering
 the same  risks.  The choice of indemnification will defer the  actual
 expenditure until after the harm has occurred  and,  depending upon  the
 financing structure  used, may  also place the expenditure  In some
 budget other  than  that of  the  demonstration  project.   Such  costs,
 however,  should properly be internalized to  the  demonstration  project
 program  if  a  decision is made  to provide government funding of such
 costs.  Where  coverage  is  needed,  its cost should be absorbed  by EPA
 in the same way, and only  to the same extent,  as  other innovative
 technology  costs.  Thus, the principal rationales for  using indemnifi-
cation rather  than commercial  insurance  would  be  that  such  insurance
 Is commercially unavailable, that  the premium  costs are comparatively
much higher than indemnification expenditures would be, or  that there
are significant benefits to deferring the expenditure.

        Since  much of the  innovative technology  that is the subject of
demonstration  grants Is designed to operate at the  "end of  the pipe,"
                                 -63-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 any continuing harms to be incurred  are often remediable merely by
 removing the device  being  demonstrated.  After such a removal, the
 host source is often no worse  off, other than any liability incurred,
 than if  it  had needed to invest  in conventional technology in the
 first  place.  Since  its Investment in the demonstration technology is
 small  or zero, the host source's losses from failure of that technol-
 ogy will often be readily  absorbed by the pollution control equipment
 manufacturer,  who is hoping that the demonstration project will prove
 successful.

         Only in the  case where actual production processes must be
 altered  to  accommodate  the demonstration project technology and
 altered  back when the technology fails, will the host source suffer a
 substantial  loss for the failure.  In such circumstances,  the purchase
 of  private  insurance may be more appropriate than an offer of indemni-
 fication by  EPA.  While the type of  coverage required may  be unusual
 and costly,  this reflects  thu  relative rarety of the need  for
 coverage, and  hence  also for indemnification.

         The  future of the  use  of demonstration projects to spur the
 use of Innovative and alternative technology under the Clean Air Act
 is  very  uncertain at this  point, however, recent budget cuts have
 reduced  the  funding  for demonstration projects to the point that it
 may no longer  be a viable  stimulus.   The predictions of budget support
 for demonstration projects may indicate that support for an indemnifi-
 cation program would be lacking.

         In  the absence  of  either construction grant funding or demon-
 stration project grants, it is still theoretically possible that
 indemnification would be desirable,  If there were a sufficient regula-
 tory or  commercial Incentive for the use of  innovative technology, and
 the  risk of  failure  or  equipment damage were deemed to be  a deter-
mining impediment.   While  the  evidence does  not Indicate that a
 situation of this type  has yet arisen, use of Indemnification might be
considered more closely if the circumstances seem to warrant it.  At
 this point,  the need for indemnification has not been shown in the air
pollution control context*

         The  technological-feasibility problems presented by RCRA
differ from  those of other innovative technology programs  principally
in  that  the  existing implementation  barriers to hazardous  waste treat-
ment, storage  or disposal  technology development appear to be economic
rather than  technical.   Thus,  the ample list of unused or  underuti-
lized hazardous-waste technologies derives,  not from their need to be
demonstrated or improved,  but  from their relatively high cost, com-
pared to conventional disposal practices.  The main barrier to
improved technology  is  the lack  of demand for that technology at its
current  price.  That  price,  in turn,  reflects not only the relative
complexity of  the improved  technology,  compared to conventional
measures, but  also the  difficulties  of siting the technology in the
face of  public  opposition.
                                 -64-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Sect lo'n "ill
        For this reason, it may be unreasonable  to  believe  that  a  pro-
nise of indemnification would substantially  alter  the  net  Impact of
existing Incentives and barriers  to hazardous  waste technology  imple-
mentation.  The magnitude of the  other  factors influencing  hazardous
waste technology decision making  appears  to  be so much greater  than
the magnitude of the risk of technology failure,  that  Indemnification
can be expected to alter decision processes  In only rare circum-
stances.

    e.  Conclusion

        Use of Indemnification as an  incentive to encourage use  of
innovative technology In either the air pollution or hazardous waste
areas has limited potential applicability.   Based upon current
evidence, the extension of a § 202(a)(3)  type  of  indemnification to
other EPA Program areas does not  seem warranted.
                                 -65-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
        D.   INDEMNIFICATION UNDER  §  113(b)  OF THE CLEAN AIR ACT

 1.   Legislative  History  and Background

     a.   Introduction  to  §  H3(b)

         Section  113 of  the Clean  Air  Act80 provides  the primary
 enforcement  authority pertaining  to stationary  source  requirements of
 the  Clean  Air  Act.  Section 113(a)  provides for administrative notices
 of violation and  orders; § 113(b) provides for  civil relief;  § 113(c)
 provides for criminal relief; and § 113(d) provides  for delayed
 compliance orders*

         Section  113(b),  requires  EPA  in  certain cases,  and authorizes
 it in others,  to  bring a civil  action for  an Injunction or for a civil
 penalty, or  both.  It also provides for  partial indemnification In the
 case of  unreasonable  enforcement:

               [l]n the case of  any  action  brought by the
               Administrator under this subsection, the  Court
               may award costs of  litigation (including
               reasonable attorney and expert witness fees)
               to  the  party or parties against whom such
               action  was brought  In any  case where the  court
               finds that such action  was unreasonable.

         This provision was enacted  as a  part of the  1977 Clean Air Act
 Amendments,  which Instituted major  changes to the basic federal
 enforcement  scheme established  in 1970.°l   The  1970  Amendments
 stressed administrative enforcement at the federal level for  the first
 time under federal pollution control  legislation.  By  1977 EPA had
 proceeded  with hundreds of administrative  enforcement  actions to
 require  compliance with applicable  emission limitations.  However,
 some of  these  actions, for practical  reasons, lengthened compliance
 timetables past deadlines  established in the 1970 Amendments.  The
 1977 Amendments substantially constrained  EPA's enforcement authority
 by limiting  the criteria under  which  such  extensions might be granted
 (§ 113(d)) and by requiring  that EPA  go  to court  to  obtain long-term
 injunctlve relief, at the  same  time,  Congress provided  a judicial
 civil penalty  mechanism to facilitate economic  sanctions for  unwar-
 ranted compliance delays.   These amendments seemed to  forecast more
 substantial  reliance  on judicial enforcement by the  agency; therefore,
 it is not  surprising  that  Congress  would have included  a provision
under $  113  designed  to constrain unreasonable  enforcement litiga-
 tion.82

    b.  Legislative History to  the  §  113(b)  Indemnity Provision

        Section 113(b)'s indemnification provision originated in the
House Interstate and  Foreign Commerce Committee as an amendment to
                                 -66-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 H.R.  10498  in  the 94th  Congress  (1976 session).83  The House Committee
 Report  on  that  bill  explained  that  the provision was Intended to pro-
 tect  parties against "wholly unwarranted enforcement actions" and to
 restrain "overzealous enforcement;" the report also commented that,
 "Only If the bringing of  the action Is arbitrary, capricious, frivo-
 lous, harassing, or  wholly without  basis in fact or law should the
 court consider  such  an  action  'unreasonable'."8^  The Senate followed
 the House version, as did the  Conference Committee.

         No  bill was  ultimately enacted In 1976.   When Congress began
 again in 1977,  the House  bill  did not include the indemnity provision
 under §  113(b).  Instead  it arose in the Senate.  As introduced and
 ultimately  enacted,  It  was identical to the 1976 House version.  The
 Report  of the Senate Committee on Environment and Public Works
 explained,  simply, "The intent of the provision  is to prevent harass-
 ment  of  parties by the  Government."85  The Conference Report provided
 no further  explanation.""

    c.   Legislative  Issues Involving Indemnification

         There is very little.recorded debate in  the legislative
 history  on  the  issue of indemnification;  and no  mention is  made of
 specific circumstances  warranting the inclusion  of such a provision  in
 1977 Amendments.  However, the issue has been debated in other
 contexts, as discussed  below.

         (1) Background

            The American  private litigation system is one of the few
 in the world that do not  award court costs and attorney fees to the
 prevailing  party as  a matter of course.   The "American Rule," removes
 a potential barrier  to  litigation.   A party must expect to  pay his own
 way, win or lose, but he  need  not forego a legitimate cause of action
 out of  fear that he  may lose and incur the litigation costs of his
 opposition.  The rule thus reflects a strong American orientation
 toward  the  importance of encouraging litigation.87  In this view the
 power to litigate is  the  power to ensure not only that the  law is
 applied, but that it  is continually refined to suit new or  changed
 circumstances.

            Discretionary exceptions to the American Rule are recog-
 nized in at least three broad  categories;  (1) to penalize frivolous  or
 intentionally harassing litigation,  delay tactics, and other actions
 amounting to abuse of process; (2)  to effect an  equitable distribution
of litigation costs  when  the litigant has performed a benefit for a
 larger class of persons (e.g., a stockholder suit that benefits all
 stockholders); and (3)  to encourage litigation to facilitate accom-
 plishment of statutory  goals (e.g.,  encouragement of the public to act
 as private attorneys  general where  statutes expressly allow for such
an award).  In  all three categories,  the exception continues to pro-
                                 -67-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 mote  the  underlying philosophy  of  the  American Rule by discouraging
 unwarranted  litigation  (in the  case  of the first)  and by encouraging
 desirable litigation that  might otherwise be unaffordable (in the case
 of  the  last  two).     These exceptions  are BO well  established as to be
 considered part  of  the  Rule.

             According to  the  principle of sovereign immunity, the
 government is  subject only to such legal  claims as it may expressly
 allow by  legislation.   Although there  are a fairly large number of
 statutes"' in  which Congress  has authorized recovery of attorneys'
 fees  among private  litigants, few  statutes have allowed recovery
 against the  Federal Government  and even fewer in enforcement cases.
 Most  EPA  implemented statutes,  for example, allow  recovery of attor-
 neys' fees by  citizens  who sue  to  require the Administrator to perform
 a nondiscretionary  duty,90 but  only  the Clean Air  Act and the Toxic
 Substances Control  Act  allow  recovery  of  attorneys'  fees in other cir-
 cumstances,  and  only the Clean  Air Act allows recovery in an enforce-
 ment  action.

             In 1981,  however, Congress enacted general legislation
 waiving immunity for attorneys'  and  expert witness'  fees.  This legis-
 lation, the  Equal Access to Justice  Act,  applies to all litigation by
 and against  the  Federal Government involving small business (it also
 applies to certain  formal  administrative  adjudications).^1  Its pri-
 mary  purpose is  to  erase an economic barrier to legitimate litigation
 although  the legislative history also  indicates that small industry
 may be more  susceptible to unfair  litigation tactics pursued by the
 government.  ^  This statute applies  to all EPA programs,  including
 enforcement  under the Clean Air Act.

        (2)  Section 113(b)  in Contrast to Other Approaches

            Key  aspects of  the  § 113(b) indemnification option are
 that  the  award is discretionary, It  may be made only to the party or
 parties against  whom the enforcement action is brought (i.e., not to
 the Administrator),  it may  be made only where the  court finds that
 such  action was  "unreasonable,"  and  the award for  attorney and expert
witness fees must be  "reasonable."

             (a)  The American Rule

                 Under  the  American  Rule  an award  is usually made only
 if a  party ultimately prevails,  and  it  is not necessarily conditioned
on a  determination  that the action was unreasonable  (for  example, an
award might be made  if a large  class of persons has  benefited by the
suit).  Conceivably, a successful  defense to EPA enforcement might
benefit other  potential defendants,  for example, by  exposing the
weakness  or error in an underlying regulation.   However,  an award for
this  reason  is not  allowed  under § 113(b).
                                  -68-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
                  The  question  of  restricting  the award only to pre-
vailing  parties  arose as  a  legislative  issue  on several occasions
under  the  1977 Amendments — relating  to  §  307  as well as § 113(b).
Ultimately,  this restriction was  rejected on  the basis that a har-
assing suit  might  nevertheless be won  by  the  government, and that a
suit under §  307 may  provide a benefit  to others even if It is lost by
the plaintiff.   In both cases  the legislative objective would be
thwarted by  denying attorneys'  fees, perhaps  on the basis of a simple
legal  technicality.93

                 Under the  American Rule  a  much clearer concept of
"unreasonable" agency action than exists  under  § 113(b) has evolved.'^
Under  the  "bad faith"  exception,  action meriting such an award is
almost always limited  to  circumstances  when the judge perceives an
intent to harass or delay — in other words,  action amounting to an
abuse of process.   The policy  behind the  American Rule approach is to
establish a  disincentive  to misconduct, but also to preserve existing
incentives to litigate (the fundamental purpose of the rule); thus,
litigation pursued in  good  faith  should not be  restrained even if it
may later prove  to be  unfounded,  but litigation pursued in bad faith
should be restrained.^

             (b)  The  Surface Mining Control and Reclamation Act

                 Section  S2S(e) of the  Surface  Mining Control and
Reclamation  Act^  is  the  only  other federal environmental protection
statute  that allows an award of attorneys'  and  expert witness*  fees in
the context  of enforcement.  In contrast  to § 113(b), it allows a dis-
cretionary award by the Secretary for costs resulting from administra-
tive proceedings,  including formal as well  as informal adjudications,
and by a court for judicial review of those proceedings.  Judicial
enforcement  proceedings,  however, are not expressly covered.

                 According  to  § 525(e), an  award may be made to either
party ". . .as  the court . .  . deems proper."   Both the legislative
history and  implementing  regulations promulgated by the Department of
Interior's Office  of  Surface Mining (OSM) make  it clear that an award
should be made only when  the proceeding has been initiated "in bad
faith and for the  purpose of harassing  or embarassing the permit-
tee."^7  The clear purpose  of  the provision was to establish a disin-
centive to such  action.   Although several petitions have been filed
under this section, no award has  yet been made.98

                 A major  difference between § 113(b) and § 525(e), as
interpreted and  applied by  OSM  is that  an award may be made under
§ 525(e) for costs  during administrative  proceedings.  Another varia-
tion pertains to what  circumstances justify an  award.  The language of
§ 113(b) requires  a finding that  the action was "unreasonable;"
§ 525(e), on the other hand, only requires  that the award be deemed
"proper."  The legislative  history to § 525(e), however,  strongly sup-
                                 -69-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section  III
 ports  an  Interpretation  consistent  with  the  American  Rule  —  that  an
 award  he  made  when  the action  is  frivolous or  for  harrassraent;  and  it
 has  heen  restricted  by rule  only  to circumstances  clearly  involving
 bad  faith."

            (c)  The Equal Access to Justice Act

                 The Equal Access to Justice Act 100 provides  for
 attorneys' fees awards to small businesses and,  like  the Surface
 Mining Control and Reclamation Act,  authorizes  such awards in admi-
 nistrative as  well as judicial actions,  although the  administrative
 actions are restricted to formal adjudications.  When administrative
 action Is involved,  the  award  is mandatory,  subject to demonstration
 that the  agency position was substantially justified  or that  special
 circumstances  make the award unjust.   The result Is the same  when
 judicial  action Is involved; in addition, sovereign Immunity  Is
 waived, and the common law adopted  for circumstances  not already
 covered under  the Act.   In both cases a  party must prevail to receive
 an award.  Guidance  is given on how to determine reasonable fees.   An
 agency may pay from  appropriated funds,  and  funds  are specifically
 authorized for that  purpose.

                 Since § H3(b) of  the Clean Air Act  does  not cover
 administrative actions,  the Equal Access to  Justice Act expands the
 circumstances  where  attorneys' fees  can  be recovered  under Clean Air
 Act proceedings (although formal adjudications  occur  in only  a few
 narrow circumstances under the Act).   With respect to judicial
 enforcement, § 113(b) may be in conflict with the  new statute,  since
 it allows for  discretion In making  the awards and  since the § 113(b)
 standard may be somewhat more  favorable  to the  agency (although this
 would be a matter of interpretation).

                 Substantial legislative debate was given  to  the issue
 of what circumstances would justify  an award under the new Act. A
 purely discretionary standard, similar to the Surface Mining  Control
 and Reclamation Act  and  the American  Rule, was  rejected in part
 because it was thought that an agency would  be  reluctant to award  fees
 against itself in an agency proceeding.  It  was also  thought  that an
 agency required more specific legislative direction.1^1

                 Also rejected was  a  standard proposed by  the Depart-
ment of Justice, that would limit recovery to circumstances in which
 the government action was "arbitrary,  frivolous, unreasonable,  or
groundless, or the United States continued to litigate after  it
 clearly became so."  It  was thought  that this standard would  be too
difficult for  the regulated party to  prove.  Instead,  the  burden was
 shifted to the government to prove  that  its  action was "substantially
 justified" (or that  other special circumstances would make an award
unjust).102
                                 -70-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
                  According  to  a  Department  of  Justice  spokesperson,
 only  one  petition has  been  filed  to  date  (the  effective  date of the
 Act was October  1,  1981).   The Department  is currently processing that
 claim.103

 2.  Application  to  Date

    a.  Cases

        There  is  only  one case to date  In which  an  award under
 §  113(b)  has been made or requested.10^  This  case  involved  Apache
 Powder Co., a  manufacturer  of explosives in Arizona, who had been
 cited by  both  the State agency and EPA  for  violating Arizona nitric
 acid  plant emission requirements.10^  Compliance problems were docu-
 mented as early  as  1972 by  the state, and In response  to a request for
 assistance by  the State, EPA began documenting violations soon after.
 Ultimately, both  the State  and EPA agreed to a compliance plan which
 involved  replacement of the noncoraplying facility and  retirement  by
 January,  1976.   When,  as late as  1978,  the  facility was  still
 operating in violation of emission requirements,  EPA initiated a  suit
 to recover civil  penalties, to require  compliance with the Arizona
 regulation and to enforce a § 113 abatement order previously issued  by
 the Agency.

        Apache moved for summary  judgment on the  ground  that EPA  had
 failed to approve variances submitted by the State  to  EPA,  which,  if
 approved, would  have excused the violation.  Although  information  is
 not clear on the  point, it  seems  that during consideration of this
 motion, Department  of Justice lawyers determined  that  an independent
 basis for challenging  the case existed — that EPA  had not satisfied a
 jurisdictlonal prerequisite to the action by approving the underlying
 regulation as a  part of the State Implementation  Plan.   Although  the
 Regional EPA Office argued  that the regulation had  been  approved,  the
 Department, with  EPA concurrence, filed a Confession of  Error and
 agreed to pay costs and counsel fees.

        A review  of the reported facts  in the  case  and subsequent
 legal proceedings indicates a strong likelihood  that throughout all  of
 the proceedings  the Agency  acted in good faith.   The potential proce-
dural deficiency  that  resulted in withdrawal from litigation had  been
 identified by regional lawyers long before  initiation  of litigation,
and had been resolved on the basis of legal arguments  that probably
would not be considered frivolous.10^

    b.  Indemnification Factors

        (1) Administration

            There is no indication in the Apache  Powder  case that
administration of the  indemnity provision was  burdensome or  presented
                                 -71-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 specific  problems.   Costs  of  litigation are normally fairly easily
 documented.   While  one  might  anticipate dispute over the issue of
 whether  specific  costs  are "reasonable," a Department of Justice
 attorney  Indicated  that consideration of such claims is routine, not
 time-consuming, and rarely controversial.  When they are controver-
 sial,  he  indicated  that courts  generally follow the Department's
 recommendation, and the controversy is usually resolved without a
 substantial  additional  effort by the Department.  The preferred route
 Is  to  negotiate a proposed award out-of-court. ^'

             A General Accounting Office staff person, who actually
 processes  the award,  indicated  that payment is also a very simple
 administrative procedure.   Notice of the Award is  forwarded by the
 Department,  and a check is drawn on the Judgment Fund of the U.S.
 Treasury.  This fund, which supplies wide-ranging  claims, is main-
 tained at  a  high  enough level so that attorneys' fee awards represent
 an  almost  insignificant depletion.^8

        (2)  Financing

             The financing  mechanism for § 113(b) is through the Judg-
 ment Fund, authorized by 31 U.S.C.  § 72A(a) for the purpose of paying
 judgments  against the United  States, administered  by the GAO,  and
 financed  from general revenues.   According to a GAO staff person,
 Congress  routinely  replenishes  the  fund with specific appropriations
 and does not usually  scrutinize  individual payouts.^9  Since this fund
 serves as  a  reservoir for  judgments and fees in a  wide range of cases,
 it  is  doubtful that the costs in a  single claim for attorneys'  fees
 would  be significant  in comparison  to all claims against the fund.

        (3)  Costs

             Approximately  $10,000 was awarded Apache Powder in fees
 and costs.*10 These  were  considered reasonable and in line with costs
 Incurred in  suits of  similar  scope  and duration according to a
 Department of Justice attorney.*"   Since this is  the only award to
 date,  the  total costs of Implementing the § 113(b) indemnity provision
 are probably not  significant.  There is no indication that EPA resour-
 ces have been devoted to the  provision — no regulations address the
 provision, and persons  Interviewed  were not aware  of any formal or
 informal agency efforts to consider the provision; Indeed, no agency
 policy memoranda  which  address  indemnification under § 113(b)  could be
 identified.

        (4)  Alternative Relief Mechanisms

             The experience to date  suggests § 113(b) provides a relief
mechanism  that is not required.   This is Indicated primarily by the
 infrequency  of awards (one).  However,  it may also be reflected in
 recent agency indications  that air  pollution enforcement for station-
ary sources  will  shift  more toward  a State assistance role.112

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section  III
         (5)  Equity,  Fairness,  Due Process

             Although §  113(b)  provides  partial  relief  to  a  person who
has  suffered wrongdoing on  the part  of  EPA,  this  is  not  its major
purpose.   Rather,  Congress  intended  primarily  that §  113(b) deter the
Agency  from  future wrongdoing;  and the  award of attorney  fees  works
both as  an Incentive to the economically disadvantaged  party to  raise
legitimate defenses  to  unreasonable  litigation, and  as  a  disincentive
to unreasonable  litigation  in  the first place.  By compensating  for
the  smaller  inequity (unreasonabale  litigation  costs)  §  113(b)  pre-
vents the  larger inequity (submission to unreasonable  enforcement
without  defense).  Viewed In this manner,  an award in Apache Powder
would not  have been  appropriate if Apache  would have defended  anyway.
This would have  been the case,  according to  an  attorney who repre-
sented Apache during the proceedings.*•"

             It should also  be  noted  that the company considered  the
amount of  the award  to  be satisfactory.^*  It  was not  determined,
however, whether additional uncompensated  expenses were incurred, or
whether  the  company  feels that  attorney costs  (and other  costs)  prior
to litigation deserve compensation.  EPA's enforcement  action  began
almost five  years  prior to  the  1978  court  action.  During that  time,
extensive  negotiations  occurred between the  company and EPA.   Evidence
strongly indicates,  however, that negotiations  with  the state  agency
would have continued to occur  in any case, and  that  the company  may
not have reduced its overall resource commitment  In  these negotiations
even if  EPA  had  not  been involved.

         (6)  Statutory Indemnification Objectives

            A primary purpose  of the indemnity  provision  was to  reduce
the likelihood for "unreasonable" enforcement  litigation  by EPA.   Fee
shifting might accomplish this  by allowing for  an effective defense,
where no defense (or an ineffective  defense) would otherwise be
pursued:   knowledge  that a  defendant would pursue its case  might  deter
the Agency from  using litigation as  an  unwarranted threat;  pursuit of
a' legitimate defense would  also protect against a miscarriage  of
justice; finally,  a  fee payment obligation might  serve as an economic
or moral deterrent to unreasonable litigation.

            Apache Powder alone provides little basis  for testing the
objectives of §  113(b).Even  If one assumes that as a  result  of
Apache Powder more careful  attention would be given  to  state implemen-
tation plan  status in future cases,  It  is  not clear what  role  the
indemnity  clause has played.   It does not  appear  that the agency
action was taken in  bad faith.  Furthermore,  discussions with agency
officials  indicate greater  embarassraent over having to abandon  the
case than  over the payment.115   In addition, it Is likely that Apache
Powder would have  pursued its  defense even if no  such award were
allowable.116
                                 -73-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
             The  infrequency  of  §  113(b)'s  usage (only one case to
 date)  may  be viewed  as  an  Indication  that  the  provision is not neces-
 sary.   Although  it  could also be  viewed  as an  indication that the
 provision  Is actually working effectively  as a deterrent, this inter-
 pretation  is of  doubtful merit.   Most agency persons interviewed were
 either unaware that  the indemnity clause existed,  or indicated that It
 had  never  been actively considered when  planning and pursuing litiga-
 tion.   Internal  clearance  procedures  are so rigorous .that there is
 very little  risk that actions will be groundless.H7

             Further, a  review of  recent  congressional hearings and
 other  reports involving the  Clean Air Act  and  numerous interviews with
 Industry representatives disclosed little  evidence that EPA judicial
 enforcement  is viewed as harassing, erroneous  or without legal justi-
 fication. H8 The vast  majority of all cases filed under § 113(b), in
 fact,  go to  court in the form of  negotiated consent decrees.H*
 Finally, If  the  indemnity  clause  is needed to  encourage companies to
 defend  against the agency  when  the imbalance of litigation resources
 would  otherwise  be dissuasive,  then one  would  expect to see more
 reliance on  the  provision  than has occurred.

        (7)  Impact on Other  Statutory Missions

             An area of  concern  in any prospective  Indemnification
 program, especially those  designed to have an  impact on specific
 agency  actions,  is whether the program will result in other unintended
 adverse impacts.  A logical  area  of concern under  § 113(b) would be
 the  potential for interference with EPA  enforcement objectives.   There
 has  been no  indication, however,  that the  indemnification provision of
 § 113(b) has had either a  positive or a  negative impact on enforcement
 under  the  Clean  Air Act.

 3.   Summary  Assessment  of  §  113(b)

     a.  It Is Questionable Whether The Indemnity Provision In §  113(b)
        Is Needed To Accomplish Congressional  Purposes.

        Concern  over the potential  for harassing,  or otherwise
 "unreasonable" enforcement litigation under the Clean Air Act seems
 unfounded.   Only one case  has Involved such an award,  and research
 disclosed  few instances of complaint  regarding the good faith of,  or
errors  involving EPA enforcement  litigation.   In fact,  the great
majority of  enforcement actions are resolved by negotiated consent
 decree.  In  addition, EPA  budget  requests,  enforcement  clearance pro-
cedures, and other air  program guidance  within EPA suggest that  liti-
gation occurs only after rigorous  screening procedures  designed  to
ensure  that  it is justified.  Finally, it  is doubtful that the § 113(b)
 fee-shifting provision would actually serve as a disincentive to
unreasonable litigation, since EPA is not  accountable for the fee
under the  present system.  A ruling against EPA on the  case would pro-
bably be a more  persuasive deterrent.
                                 -74-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
         Experience  to  date  also does  not support the need for an
 •Indemnity  provision to overcome an inequitable distribution of litiga-
 tion  resources  between EPA  and  enforcement case defendants*  Even if
 such  an  inequity  has existed,  the  limited usage of  § 113(b)'s indem-
 nity  clause  indicates  that  the  inequity has been an unimportant factor
 in  Judicial  enforcement proceedings.   Although it Is possible that
 such  limited usage  has occurred because the indemnity provision provi-
 des an insufficient enticement  to  defend, the more  likely reason is
 that  enforcement  cases have been justifiable.  Few  cases, in fact,
 have  occurred which were not settled  by consent decree.   Agency
 spokespersons also  expressed their sentiment that inequities do not
 actually exist  — industry  that is subject to enforcement litigation
 normally has more resources for defense at its disposal  than the
 Agency has for  prosecution.  This  view could not be confirmed with
 actual data, however.

    b.  Potential Problem Areas

        (1) Definition of "Unreasonable" Enforcement

            The legislative history tends to support two interpreta-
 tions of the term "unreasonable."   In one interpretation, action may
 be  "unreasonable" only when it  is  pursued in bad faith (an interpreta-
 tion  consistent with common law application of the  American Rule on
 fee shifting).  In  the other, it may  be "unreasonable" for less
 restrictive grounds — when the action was taken in good faith, but a
 court determines  the decision to be arbitrary or without adequate
 legal basis.

        (2) Who pays?

            Under § 113(b)  the  agency is not accountable for payment.
Rather, the award is paid by GAO from the Judgment  Fund.  It is possi-
ble,  that payment by agency would  create a more significant disincen-
tive  to engage  in "unreasonable" enforcement.  There is  no present
indication, however, that a more significant disincentive (or,  in
fact, any disincentive at all)  is  needed.

        (3) Equal Access  to Justice Act Overlap

            This  overlap  exists only  to the extent  small businesses
are involved.   If so,  a "prevailing"  small business may  attempt to
obtain more favorable  treatment under the Equal Access to Justice Act
than  is provided  under §  113(b).   The award in such a case Is manda-
tory, subject to  a  demonstration by the Agency that its  enforcement
action was "substantially justified,"  or that other special factors
warrant no award.   Although the burden of proof has clearly shifted to
the agency, it may  be  possible  for the agency to argue that the sub-
stantive standards  are essentially the same as under § 113(b).
                                 -75-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 4.   The Applicability  of  the  §  113(b)  Model  to Other  EPA Statutes

     Major  characteristics of  §  113(b)  indemnification are:   (1) the
 need to restrain  unreasonable judicial enforcement  pursued  by EPA,  and
 (2)  the need  to encourage persons  to  litigate  who would otherwise
 refrain from  defending an enforcement  action In court for economic
 reasons.   While the  need  for  such  a program  under the Clean Air Act is
 not  clearly justified,  it could nevertheless be justified In enforce-
 ment litigation under  other statutes  administered by  EPA.  For most of
 the  same reasons, however, a  similar  indemnification  provision is pro-
 bably not  warranted  under other EPA statutes.

     a.  There Is Little Evidence That  Judicial Enforcement  Undertaken
        By EPA Is Arbitrary,  Harassing, Without Legal Authority,  Or
        Otherwise Unreasonable.

        Discussions  with  industry  and  agency spokespersons, and a
 review  of  current literature  disclosed very  few judicial enforcement
 cases that could be  termed "unreasonable"  in the sense that the agency
 brought the action erroneously  or  without  legal justification.*2^
 Most Industry complaints  relating  to unreasonable EPA enforcement con-
 cern underlying regulations or  policies, or  they relate to  enforcement
 target  selection or  negotiating  practices  of the Agency.

     b.  There Is No  Reason to Expect That  Ureasonable Judicial
        Enforcement  Will  Occur  in  the  Near Future.

        Although enforcement  authorities and mandates vary  among  the
 different  EPA statutes, the internal control over enforcement actions
 recommended for litigation is the  same.  This  control is rigorous,
 requiring  a careful  demonstration  of facts and legal  theories that
 must  be cleared through numerous layers of regional,  headquarters,  and
 ultimately Department  of  Justice concurring  authority.121  Interviews
 with  present  and past  enforcement  officials  indicated that  this
 screening  process works well  to  prevent unwarranted enforcement.'-22

        EPA*s enforcement policies also emphasize that only the major
 violators  will be aggressively  pursued, and  the states will be relied
 on more to fulfill the overall compliance  goals established by
 Congress.  Even the major violators will be  encouraged,  as  in the
 past, to settle out-of-court.*2-*

    c.  There is No Indication That Such a Provision  Would  Actually
        Work as a Disincentive to Unreasonable Enforcement.

        Persons involved  in the  implementation of enforcement programs
who were interviewed in the course of  research agreed that  payment  of
attorney fees for unreasonable enforcement would be irrelevant as a
disincentive  to unreasonable  litigation. Prevention of such action
would occur primarily because of the internal  clearance  proce-
dures.124
                                 -76-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section  III
         If the agency were forced  to divert  substantial  funds  from
previously authorized activities  in order  to  cover  litigation  Indem-
nities,  it is possible that this  would  serve  more as a disincentive to
litigate whenever there Is a risk  of loss, rather than as an effective
disincentive to engage In unreasonable  enforcement.^^

    d.  An Alternative Exists Which May Obviate  the Need for Extend-
        ing § 113(b) to Other Statutes, If Such  a Need Exists.

        The Equal Access to Justice Act promises an award to pre-
vailing parties in all EPA enforcement  litigation if EPA cannot
justify Its action.12°  This Act  applies only to small businesses*
However, it is the small business  that  is most likely to have  economic
reasons not to defend aggressively against EPA enforcement.  Larger
companies, which are more often subject to enforcement,  typically have
adequate resources to defend against EPA action, and the availability
of an indemnity for litigation costs will not usually be the persua-
sive factor in a decision to defend.
                                 -77-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
              E.   INDEMNIFICATION  PURSUANT TO §  311(1)  OF
                          THE  CLEAN  WATER  ACT

1 .  Legislative History And Background

    a.   Introduction  to § 311(1)

         Section 311 of the Clean  Water  Act127 ia  the primary regula-
tory mechanism under  that statute for restricting one-time or episodic
discharges of oil  and hazardous substances1^8 that may be  accidental
or intentional, and are not susceptible to regulation  by permit.   It
contains both preventive  and  remedial requirements,  as well as sepa-
rate sanctions and a  revolving fund  to  finance  cleanup.  This fund is
administered by the United States Coast Guard (USCG) and financed  by
special  appropriations, penalties,  and  moneys recovered  from respon-
sible parties.

         Section 311 's prevention  requirements are implemented by EPA
for non-transport  dischargers and by the  USCG for transport dis-
chargers.  However, its spill response  requirements  are  divided geo-
graphically:  the  USCG maintains  jurisdiction in  the coastal zone,
ports and harbors, and the Great  Lakes, while EPA maintains jurisdic-
tion in  other U.S. waters.  Other federal agencies are Involved, as
needed,  in the formulation and implementation of  a national contin-
gency
        A major portion of § 311 is structured  to ensure a  rapid,
effective response to a spill.  Its provisions  require  immediate noti-
fication when a spill occurs and impose  strict  liability (with  certain
limited defenses) on the discharger for  the costs of  cleanup.   If  the
discharger's actions are inadequate, the Federal Government may ini-
tiate cleanup on its own and later sue the discharger for reimburse-
ment.  A limit on liability exists unless the discharge Involved gross
negligence or willful misconduct.  If the discharger  is able  to assert
a defense under §§ 311(f) and (g), however, he  is not required  to
clean up.^0  TO the extent that he does clean  up, §  311(1) entitles
him to reimbursement for the reasonable  costs involved.  That section
provides:

                 (i)(l) In any case where an owner or opera-
              tor of a vessel or an onshore facility  or an
              offshore facility from which oil  or a hazar-
              dous substance is discharged in violation of
              subsection (b)(3) of this  section acts  to
              remove such oil or substance in accordance
              with regulations promulgated pursuant to  this
              section, such owner or operator shall be
              entitled to recover the reasonable costs
              incurred in such removal upon' establishing, in
              a suit which may be brought against the United
                                 -78-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
               States Government in the United States Court
               of Claims, that such discharge was caused
               solely by (A) an act of God, (B) an act of
               war, (C) negligence on the part of the United
               States Government, or (D) an act or omission
               of a third party without regard to whether
               such act or omission was or was not negligent,
               or of any combination of the foregoing causes.

                  (2) The provisions of this subsection shall
               not apply in any case where liability is
               established pursuant to the Outer Continental
               Shelf Lands Act, or the Deepwafer Port Act of
               1974.

                  (3) Any amount paid in accordance with a
               judgment of the United States Court of Claims
               pursuant to this section shall be paid from
               the funds established pursuant to subsection
               (k) of this section, ^l

         The primary benefit and legislative intent of § 311(1) is that
 it  encourages rapid cleanup by the party most knowledgeable of the
 content  and amount of a spill, and the party most likely to be first
 aware  that  it has occurred.  It accomplishes this result primarily by
 providing an economic incentive where there may be no other adequate
 Incentive to take corrective action because of the cost involved and
 the confidence that there would be no liability.132  in addition, it
 removes  a potential barrier to rapid private cleanup by postponing the
 need to  resolve potential issues of liability.*^

         Section 311(1) thus utilizes government indemnification to
 encourage a regulated party to take immediate steps to mitigate the
 harmful  impacts of a sudden pollution occurrence.  Such a program is
 potentially relevant to all areas of pollution control supervised by
 EPA where unforeseeable and unavoidable discharges might occur, and
'where  the availability of an indemnity might be persuasive in the
 encouragement of immediate mitigation efforts to avoid imminent
 environmental damage.  In such a case,  it is possible that regulated
 parties  might provide a more effective, cost efficient public service
 than the Agency assigned primary responsibility to do so.

     b.   Legislative Background

         Although the oil spill provisions of § 311 date back to the
 Oil  Pollution Act of 1924,  most of the oil spill programs in effect
 today  originated in or are modeled after the Water Quality Improvement
 Act  of 1970.134  Coverage of hazardous substances was added by the
 Federal  Water Pollution Control Act Amendments of 1972.l35  However,
 implementation of hazardous substance removal authority was delayed
                                  -79-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
until after  amendments  to  the  Clean Water Act  were enacted  in 1978,
which clarified EPA's authority  and responsibilities  relating to  the
designation  of hazardous  substances and  the determination of  harmful
quantities*13^  Currently,  however, EPA  authority over  hazardous  sub-
stance spills is exercised  primarily under the Comprehensive  Environ-
mental Response, Compensation  and  Liability Act of 1980 (CERCLA),137
and § 311 is used  primarily for  the prevention and regulation of  oil
spills.138

        The  1970 Water  Quality Improvement Act provisions relating  to
oil spills derived  from numerous House and Senate bills offered  in  the
wake of the Torrey  Canyon,  Santa Barbara,  and  other major oil spills
of the late  1960's.  Extensive congressional hearings at the  time
reviewed the adequacy of existing  statutory authority to prevent, con-
tain and remove such splllso   Ultimately,  comprehensive legislation
was developed In both the Senate and the House.  However, a § 311(1)
equivalent arose only in the Senate.*3*   This  provision was modified
slightly In  conference  and  retained as § 11(1) of the Act.14^

        Available  legislative  history does not indicate who proposed
the original Senate version of § 311(1)  or the reasons  offered at the
tlme.14^  A  further review  of  House and  Senate Hearings on  the pro-
posed legislation discloses almost no discussion of the issue and it
appears not  to have been controversial.14^  However, a primary  thrust
of oil spill cleanup policy has  always been to encourage prompt pri-
vate action.  This  policy was  articulated  in the first  "National
Multi-Agency Oil and Hazardous Materials Pollution Contingency Plan"
(September 1968), and has been repeated  in many statements  of legisla-
tive and regulatory policy  since.*43

        The Senate  report accompanying S.  7 noted simply:

                 S. 7 provides an  opportunity  for the owner
              or operator of a vessel or onshore or offshore
              facility  to immediately remove any oil  dis-
              charged.  It  is  the  intent of the committee to
              encourage removal  of oil by  the  owner or
              operator  of the  discharging  source.

                 In many instances,  the  owner  or operator of
              a vessel  or onshore  or  offshore  facility  will
              know of a discharge  prior  to any agency of the
              U.S. Government  and  be  in  the best position to
              take early action  to prevent or  minimize
              damage.   As testified to by  the  oil  and
              shipping  industry  it will  be in  the best
              Interest  of the  owner or operator to take
              immediate measures to reduce damage from  an
              oil spill.144
                                 -80-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
     c.   Other Statutory Approaches

         There are  three other  statutes  pertaining to oil spills and
 one  other  statute  pertaining  to  hazardous substance spills which are
 similar  in basic design to  §  311 of  the Clean Water Act.  These
 include, for  oil,  the  Trans-Alaska Pipeline Authorization Act of 1973
 (TAPAA),145 the Deepwater Port Act of  1974 (DWPA),14* the Outer
 Continental Shelf  Lands Act Amendments  of 1978 (OCSLA),147 and for
 hazardous  substances,  the Comprehensive Environmental Response, Com-
 pensation,  and Liability Act  of  1980 (CERCLA).148  Each of these
 statutes imposes strict liablity for certain costs associated with
 spills and  establishes a separate fund,  in part,  for the purpose of
 providing  an  effective response  to spills not adequately provided
 under §  311.

         (1) The Existing Oil Spill Fund Statutes149

            Like §  311,  each of  the  other oil spill fund statutes
 (TAPAA,  DUPA  and OCSLA)  authorizes government cleanup and provides the
 government  with a  right  to obtain reimbursement  from the responsible
 party unless  a defense is available.  Again like  § 311,  each  statute
 also establishes a  limit on liability,  so that to the extent  the limit
 is exceeded,  the fund  pays for certain  costs that might  otherwise have
 been incurred by the responsible party.

            There are  numerous differences,  however.  Most notably,
 the § 311(k)  fund  size  Is much smaller;  it  is financed primarily by
 appropriations, while  the other  funds are financed primarily  by fees
 assessed against the oil facility and vessel owners; the scope of
 liability  is  much smaller under  § 311,  excluding  property damages,
 third party cleanup costs, and other types  of claims covered  under the
 other statutes.  In addition, discharger liability limits vary, as do
 defenses that may be asserted against the government in  cleanup cost
 recovery proceedings.

            Although no  provisions identical to § 311(1) exist, both
 OCSLA and DWPA allow for the fund to cover  discharger cleanup costs  in
 two ways.   First, both  statutes  allow for a  claim against the fund  for
 such costs  If a defense  to liability exists.15^   Second, both statu-
 tes limit the discharger's liability in  such a way that  cleanup costs
 exceeding that limitation might  be charged  against the fund.  51
 TAPAA,  on the other hand, makes  the  right-of-way  holder  absolutely
 liable for  cleanup costs,^2 an
-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 to resolve these differences (along with other objectives) by pro-
 posing oil Superfund legislation.   For several years such legislation
 was proposed  and debated (most recently as H.R. 85) but never passed
 Congress. 155

            A review of  the most recent legislative debates disclosed
 no express concern over  the need for a change in approach to § 311(1)
 or to  similar provisions under the other funding statutes.  However,
 significant concern was  expressed  regarding the need for more strin-
 gent sanctions to encourage dischargers to take prompt action.15^

            Although no  provision  identical to § 311(1) emerged,  a
 somewhat  similar approach was adopted which was closer in design  to
 the OCSLA  and DWPA models.   Section 103 of H.R. 85 would have allowed
 a  claim against  the fund by the discharger for "removal" costs if a
 defense to liability existed or if such costs exceeded the statutory
 limit  on  liability.  (A  similar claim could also be made by a non-
 responsible third party.)  Under § 104 limits on liability would  not
 apply  if  the  incident were  due to  willful misconduct or gross negli-
 gence  or a violation of  applicable federal regulations, or if the
 owner  or operatior failed or refused to assist in cleanup.  Defenses
 would  have included acts of war, natural phenomena and third party
 responsibility (a "third party" would Include governmental
 entities).157

        (3) The  Comprehensive Environmental Response,  Compensation
            and  Liability Act (CERCLA)

            CERCLA addresses a much larger variety of  pollution inci-
 dents  than any of the oil spill legislation.  Ironically,  it does not
 include oil spills,  even though early initiatives supporting Superfund
 legislation were largely directed  at coordinating and  improving the
 various oil spill statutes.15®  In 1979,  however, Superfund momentum
 shifted toward hazardous substance pollution problems.  Primary con-
 gressional concern was focused on  the thousands of abandoned or Inac-
 tive hazardous waste  disposal sites which required expensive remedial
 action.  However,  concern was also expressed over chemical spills.

            In congressional Superfund hearings EPA Deputy Adminis-
 trator, Barbara  Blum  testified that as many as 1,800 hazardous sub-
 stance  spills  occur each year that are not subject to  regulation  under
 §311 because  they do not reach navigable water.15' She went on  to
 testify that  other EPA authority to deal  effectively with such inci-
dents was  also limited in some major respect — usually having to do
with funding  or  procedural  constraints.1^
                                            r
            CERCLA addressed these problems directly by providing an
extensive  funding mechanism ($1.6  billion over a five  year period,
compared to the  $35 million revolving fund under § 311(k)) and stiff
sanctions  for  failure to report a  spill or to take required cleanup

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 steps.   At the same time,  many of the other issues that have plagued
 implementation of the  oil  spill statutes were resolved.

             While CERCLA contains no provision identical to § 311(i),
 a similar result  could be  accomplished under § lll(a), which provides
 that  the President may pay any claim for necessary response costs
 incurred by any person (other than the government) as a result of
 carrying out the  national  contingency plan, so long as such costs are
 approved under the plan and certified by the responsible federal
 official.  However,  the approval requirement in this section has been
 interpreted by EPA to  require pre-authorization.^1  This requirement,
 along with a current EPA policy to authorize only a very minor amount
 of  cleanup costs  by  persons other than governmental organizations or
 approved contractors marks a significant difference between CERCLA and
 § 311(1).1^2  in  effect, these policies seriously restrict voluntary
 cleanup  action.

             Three primary  factors have been cited in support of this
 Agency position:   (I)  cleanup techniques for chemical spills (as
 opposed  to oil spills)  require highly specialized knowledge, not only
 to  prevent wasted effort,  but also to prevent mistakes that may com-
 pound the environmental threat or complicate further cleanup, or both;
 (2) containment and  cleanup action require  special safety precautions
 because  of the dangerous nature of many chemicals (more so than oil),
 and the  government should  not establish economic  incentives to engage
 in dangerous conduct,  especially when the risks may be minimized by
 encouraging the use  of  specific contractor  organizations known to have
 the requisite skills;  and  (3) it is  desirable to  maximize EPA cost
 control  in order  to  protect the fund — unanticipated cleanup costs,
 not subject to federal  supervision,  would be an unacceptable drain on
 limited  resources.  ^

             Undoubtedly, cost control is of primary significance.
 There is  a tremendous  federal incentive (reflected in the legislative
 history  to CERCLA, as  well as agency regulations)^ to require pri-
 vate  cleanup whenever  possible,  since the total anticipated cleanup
 costs, according  to  one estimate,  may exceed fund resources by several
 hundred  percent.165  Offering reimbursement for voluntary cleanup
 could result In numerous claims,  ultimately draining the fund and
 interfering with  EPA prioritization  of  fund expenditures — and per-
 haps  resulting in an unacceptable  commitment of resources to the
 administration and adjudication of claims (without preauthorization of
 expenses,  a greater  number of non-legitimate claims would be
 expected).

             Persons  directly  involved in spill cleanup, moreover, feel
 that  inherent  differences  in  the characteristics  of chemicals and oil
 increase  the  opportunity for  error and  dangerous  exposure and that the
 potential  benefit  in encouraging inexperienced private voluntary
 cleanup  in the limited  circumstances that might be managed effectively
without  preauthorization would  not justify  the risks involved.
                                 -83-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
             Nonetheless,  others  have Indicated that  the  potential  for
 increased  environmental  harm  cannot  be dismissed,  and  the  costs  of
 cleanup  for  certain  events  may be  more extensive.   It  may  be  expected
 that  spills  will occur for  which the discharger Is clearly not  liable
 and for  which he will be  unwilling to take  immediate cleanup  steps
 without  federal reimbursement.   For  some of these  spills,  federal
 cleanup  will be more difficult and cost more because of  the delay,  and
 greater  environmental damage  will  occur.

             It Is  perhaps too soon to tell  whether the approach  under
 CERCLA is  more appropriate  than  the  approach under § 311(1).  Although
 Superfund  has been in effect  for almost one and one-half years,  imple-
 mentation  has proceeded  slowly and conservatively.*-""

 2.  Application To Date

    a.   Cases167

         Since 1973 there  have been 45 cases brought  under  § 311(1)  of
 the Clean  Water Act, all  involving oil spills, and totalling  approxi-
 mately $6.3  million  in claims.   Fourteen of the cases  have resulted in
 settlement and four have  resulted  in an award by the U.S.  Court  of
 Claims.  Fourteen cases were  dismissed by the court  and  13 cases are
 currently  pending.

         Approximately 80  percent of  the cases filed  to date have
 Involved an  act or omission of a third party.   Approximately  half of
 these cases  have involved vandalism.   Over  60Z of  the  completed  third
 party cases  have been settled In favor of the plaintiff.

        Only one claim involving negligence on the part  of the U.S.
 Government has been  filed.  In that  case, the USCG wrongfully accused
 the plaintiff of an oil discharge.   The plaintiff  filed  a  claim  for
 $936, the  smallest claim  submitted to date, and the  case was  settled.
Half of  the  remaining cases (approximately  10Z of  the  total)  were
 claimed  to involve acts of God.  Half of these were  settled In favor
of the plaintiff.  Finally, eight  of  the cases involved  insurance com-
 panies that  had paid for  a loss  incurred as a result of  an oil spill
 and then sought reimbursement from the Court of Claims.

    b.  Indemnification Factors

         (1)  Costs168

             Total anticipated payments for  claims  filed  to date  are
approximately $1.2 million, or $117,000 per year for the 10 year
period.  If  1972 Is excluded  (it was  the first year  of the program  and
 there was only one case)  and  1979-1981 is also excluded  (additional
cases may  still be filed  for  these years),  the annual  average is
approximately $188,600.
                                 -84-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
             While the average claim has been about $119,000,  the
 average claim for which payment has been made was approximately
 $69,000.   The average payment to date has been $39,000.

             The future number and types of cases brought to the U.S.
 Court  of  Claims under § 311(1), and resulting costs may reasonably be
 expected  to  be similar to those submitted to date.  There is  always
 the  possibility that  a very large case will be filed which greatly
 modifies  the payments for a given year.  However, there have  been a
 sufficient number of  cases to date to allow for an estimate which,
 over the  long run,  should be fairly accurate.

             In addition to payments of claims, additional costs are
 incurred  in  administering the program.  Most of these involve Depart-
 ment of Justice lawyers responsible for defending against the claims
 and Court of Claims adjudication costs.  In addition, there are minor
 costs  involved in administering the revolving fund under § 311(k).
 These  costs  are not readily available for inclusion in this report.

             Although  the costs to date and predictable future costs
 are not insignificant,  no basis has been identified for concluding
 that the  costs are  unacceptable In view of the benefits derived.  In
 fact,  the actual reimbursed cleanup costs incurred by the discharger
 may be  less  than what they would be if the state or Federal Government
 were to conduct the cleanup.   This is not simply because the  private
 polluter  may be able  to manage cleanup more efficiently, but  because
 the delayed  reaction  time inherent in government initiation of cleanup
 may result in greater costs because of the Increased difficulty
 involved  in  containment and removal.   However, this is a matter of
 speculation,  and no data was  available which addressed this issue.

        (2)  Financing

             The financing mechanism for § 311(1) Is through § 311(k)
 which  establishes a revolving fund operated by the USCG and financed
 through a combination of appropriations,  penalties against §  311
 violators, and  costs  recovered by the government.   The fund,  which Is
 currently maintained  at $35 million,  is available for all cleanup
 action, including reimbursement under § 311(1),  federal cleanup, and
 certain state and local activities as well.

            Although  it was hoped initially that the combination of
 penalties and  federal  cost  recoveries would be sufficient to  replenish
 the fund, this  has not  happened.   Based In part  on this experience,
 funds established to  finance  cleanup  In subsequent legislation (the
Outer Continental Shelf Land's Act,  Deep Water Port Act, Trans-Alaska
 Pipeline Authorization  Act, and CERCLA) are financed in large part by
 special fees  imposed  on potential dischargers.  Proposed oil  spill
 Superfund legislation  (H.R. 85) would also follow these later models.
                                 -85-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
             The  total  payout  associated with § 311(1)  to date,  approx-
 imately  $700,000,  appears  to  represent  a small burden  on the §  311(k)
 fund  and  would not in  itself  appear  to  justify revision of the
 financing system for such  payments.

         (3)  Administration

             The  administration  of  claims under § 311(1) Is straight-
 forward.   Suit is  filed  in the  Court of Claims.  An adversary pro-
 ceeding  ensues,  with Department of Justice lawyers representing the
 § 311(k)  fund.   Claims may be settled;  judgments are appealable;  and
 payments  are made  by the USCG from the  § 311(k) fund upon presentation
 of a  request In  accordance with 33 C.F.R.  § 153.411.

             Persons from the USCG  have  suggested,  however, that the
 Court of  Claims  procedure  may be too lengthy and cumbersome for the
 small number of  cases  involved.  Docket delays occur,  and resolution
 of many  cases might occur  sooner If  less formal or non-adversarial
 procedures were  utilized to consider whether prerequisites to recovery
 are met.   It is  possible that these  delays interfere with a primary
 statutory objective — that the promise of recovery serve as an incen-
 tive  for  the non-liable discharger to take rapid cleanup steps.
 However,  this could not be documented.

             In other circumstances involving statutory incentives to
 proceed  rapidly  with oil spill  cleanup  (e.g.,  the Outer Continental
 Shelf Lands  Act, the Deepwater  Port  Act, and the Trans-Alaska Pipeline
 Authorization Act) funds available for  private cleanup efforts  are
 financed  primarily by a fee levied against the owner of the oil,  and
 claims procedures  are administered by the  agency or a  third party.
 Although  this alternative  might allow for  a more efficient processing
 of claims  under  §  311(1),  the USCG may  be  reluctant to assume such
 duties:   the budget implications would  probably be considered unfavor-
 able; furthermore, the USCG has  traditionally  viewed claims adjustment
 as an area of responsibility that  is inconsistent  with and might
 detract  from its primary operational duties, and the USCG has con-
 tended in  the past that it  does  not  have adequately trained persons to
 assume such  duties.*"'

         (4) Fairness, Equity, Due  Process

            Fairness is not ordinarily  an  issue for consideration in
 the Incentive Indemnification situation, because the purpose of the
mechanism  Is not to remedy  some  inequity that  may  have occurred,  but
 to encourage a nonliable discharger  to  assist  in eliminating an
environmental hazard.  However,  experience indicates that an inequity
periodically occurs.  Occasionally,  the USCG makes a tentative  deter-
mination  that a  party is liable, that party proceeds with cleanup, and
 later it  is  determined that some other  party was actually responsible.
Often, in  such a case, the  discharger Is not certain whether or not he
                                 -86-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Section  III
is  responsible, and  the  need  for  immediate  response  does  not  allow
time  for determining  liability  prior  to  initiating cleanup.   It  is
also  possible  that  the Federal  Government will  clean up a spill,  then
assess and collect  costs  from a party erroneously determined  to  be
responsible (the USCG reports that  this  happened on  one o-casion)

        In both cases the party may turn to  §  311(1) to be indemnified
for the government  error.  However, If it turns out  that  the  party  was
not the discharger,  he cannot recover, since §  311(1)  limits  recovery
only  to a discharger.m  This  restriction  does not  exist under  OCSLA
and was not Included  In H.R. 85.

        (5) Statutory Indemnification Objectives

            Section  311(1) has  worked to encourage timely,  cost-
effective private cleanup of certain  oil spill  incidents  and  thus has
fulfilled its  primary purpose on  those occasions.  However, the  small
number of claims since 1972 (45)  compared to the large number of
reportable oil spills since 1972  (one estimate  exceeds 125,OOO)172
indicates that § 311(1) is not  a  major factor  in accomplishing
cleanup.  Most cleanup is initiated by the  federal,  state or  local
government, or by a  responsible party who admits or  is found  to  be
liable for cleanup  by the government  or  who  is  Ineligible for indemni-
fication.173

            This suggests that  other  mechanisms utilized  under § 311
designed to accomplish cleanup  or establish  cleanup  incentives have
been  working well (e.g., national contingency  plan,  surveillance,
notification,  state  indemnification,  penalty provisions,  etc.).   Most
oil spills are now detected relatively quickly  and cleanup usually
occurs, although whether cleanup  is always  effective is a matter of
debate.174

            With respect to chemical  spills, there is  no  record  of  any
attempt to obtain reimbursement under §  311(1). Yet,  such spills have
occurred in significant numbers during the  years since enactment of
§-311.175  Several  factors appear to  account for this. First,
§ 311(1) could not actually be  used for  chemical spills until
September 28,  1979,  when EPA promulgated regulations on reportable
quantities for hazardous substances — a necessary prerequisite  to
determining the existence of a  violation under  § 311(b)(3), which,  in
turn,  is a precondition to a cause of action for a claim  under
§ 311(i)(l).   Second, EPA and the USCG have  traditionally discouraged
unsupervlsed private  response efforts Involving chemical  spills
because of the complexity and dangers involved.
                                 -87-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
             Other possible  explanations  for the limited  use  of
 § 311(1)  involving chemical  spills  include:

             •     Until  recently  very  little containment  and  removal
                  action was  considered  possible for  chemical spills.

             •     When small  spills  are  Involved (most  chemical  spills
                  are small  In  comparison to oil spills)  the  cost  of
                  cleanup rarely  merits  the  cost of pursuing  a claim
                  under  § 311(1).

             •     Since  enactment  of CERCLA  (December 11,  1980)  the
                  USCG and EPA  have  relied on CERCLA  for  response  to
                  chemical spills, rather than~§ 311, and  dischargers
                  may have concluded that they no longer have status
                  under  § 311(1).1>6

        (6)  Alternative Mechanisms

             Primary alternatives  to § 311(1)  include (1)  more elabo-
 rate  surveillance and response capability on the part  of  government,
 (2) more  effective spill disincentives and  spill prevention  regula-
 tions;  (3) more effective private cleanup incentives;  and (4) elimina-
 tion  of the  Incentive altogether  along with  substitution  of  a
 provision requiring absolute liablity for cleanup.

             (a)   Expanded Government Surveillance and  Response

                  Improvements  in  government  surveillance  of  and
 response  to  oil and chemical spills have been areas  of continual  pro-
 gress.  As a practical  matter, however,  budget  and other  administra-
 tive  constraints  virtually eliminate effective  governmental  oil spill
 response  management without discharger assistance.   It Is well
 accepted  that all of the reportable oil  spills  (over 8,000 a year
 according to one  estimate)^" and their  location (throughout most of
 the states and territorial waters) could not  be effectively  addressed
 by available governmental response resources.   This, in addition  to
 the fact  that the discharger is most often  in the best position to
 take  effective immediate mitigating action,  has resulted  in  the
 current legislative strategies to promote private action  —  strict
 liability for government cleanup except  when  certain defenses apply,
 and when  those defenses  apply, compensation  under §  311(1).

                  While  It is conceivable that  the government might
 undertake cleanup In the few cases that  merit  a claim  under  § 311(1),
 there are at least two  drawbacks.  There is  a risk that in some
 Instances the failure of the discharger  to  take immediate stop-gap
measures  will create a  more complicated  and  costly cleanup problem;
also, the government would be forced to  make  an early  determination of
liability in close cases to allow for an appropriate choice  of action.
                                 -88-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 This  would  result  in  less  flexibility  and  a  greater  administrative
 burden  than currently  exists  at  the  time  that  a  spill  occurs.

             (b)  Enhanced  Spill  Prevention Strategies

                 Section 311  already gives substantial  emphasis  to
 spill prevention.178   Regulations  on oil  spill prevention currently
 exist.   *   In  addition, fines and  civil penalties  are  allowed  under
 both  §  311  and CERCLA.'80   It Is conceivable that  more  highly  sophis-
 ticated  prevention  techniques and  a  severe sanctions policy  would
 diminish spill Incidents.   However,  there  Is general agreement  that  a
 certain  number of  spills are  Inevitable,  regardless  of  the exercise  of
 preventive  care.181  As long  as  this is the  case,  spill prevention
 techniques  and measures to  encourage their application  will  never be
 adequate substitutes for spill response techniques.

             (c)  Enhanced Cleanup  Incentives

                 Alternative  Incentives are  probably inappropriate,  at
 least for non-liable dischargers,  since it has been  demonstrated Chat
 Indemnification under  § 311(i) actually works  to encourage desired
 cleanup  that might  not otherwise occur as  effectively or as  effi-
 ciently. °^  Some doubt must  remain  on this  issue, however,  in  view  of
 the different approach recently  adopted under  CERCLA for chemical
 spills.  Under CERCLA, EPA  will  allow  for  reimbursement of a non-
 liable party only  if the expenses  have been  preauthorized  as consis-
 tent with the National Contingency Plan.18-*

                 A  possible drawback to the  CERCLA approach  is  that
 certain desirable containment  and  removal  actions  could be delayed or
 would not occur because of  the time  required to obtain  preauthoriza-
 tlon and because of possible  monetary  limits that  would be Imposed on
 the private  response.  Possible  advantages,  on the other hand,  include
 more effective safety  and cost control under government supervision,
 and more effective allocation of fund  resources toward  higher  priority
 incidents.  Whether the CERCLA approach will prove to be the better,
 one.must await further experience  in the  implementation of CERCLA, and
will require in any case that  consideration  be given to differences  in
 the statutory goals of CERCLA (use of  the  fund for long-term and non-
emergency remedial activity and  hazardous  waste sites)  and to  Inherent
differences  Involving dispersal  and cleanup  characteristics  of  the
 pollutants (chemicals under CERCLA, oil under  § 311(1)).

                 Nonetheless, certain  changes  instituted in  the  oil
 spill fund statutes following §  311, as well as in CERCLA, might prove
beneficial under § 311 as mechanisms to encourage  or facilitate  pri-
vate cleanup assistance.  These  include:

                 •   Expansion of  §  311(1) to  include non-dischargers
                     (with  restrictions to prevent clearly inappropri-
                                 -89-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
                      ate or Ineffective cleanup,  or counter productive
                      profiteering).

                  •    Agency administration of claims rather than
                      administration  of  claims In  the Court of Claims.

                  •    Authority  to  order cleanup and stiff penalties
                      for failure or  refusal.

                  •    Expanded  funding  (financed,  perhaps, by potential
                      dischargers).

             (d)   Elimination of §  311(1)

                  Elimination of the  §  311(i)  incentive altogether
would  not  seem wise  without  concurrently  imposing absolute liability
for cleanup  on the owner or operator.   This liability would be neces-
sary to ensure that  the  government  Is  not solely  responsible for
cleanup when the  owner  is clearly  not  at  fault.   If the government
were solely  responsible  in such a  situation,  there would be a greater
risk of environmental and other property  damage,  not only because of
the natural  delay inherent In a notification/response system, but also
because the  government would be forced  to make  a  more careful determi-
nation of  liability  prior to any cleanup  action.   This determination
would  be necessary,  since the discharger  would  have no ability to
recoup his expenses  if he cleaned  up,  then was  able to show later on
that he was  not liable.   Since a determination  of liability would pro-
bably  be opposed  by  the  discharger,  it  could  prove to be difficult  and
time consuming, and  the  government might  be encouraged to clean up  the
spill  and  Incur the  costs involved rather than  become bogged down in
dispute over the  issue of liability.

                  The no-fault, absolute liability for clean-up alter-
native, on the other hand,  presents  a more sensitive political issue.
Presumably,  under such an alternative,  the discharger could proceed
against a  responsible third  party  for damages.  But this would not  be
an effective solution if unforeseeable  and unavoidable acts of God  or
war were involved.   In the past, Congress has rarely been willing to
impose absolute liability without  the benefit of  any defense, and has
chosen instead to adhere to  the progressive strict llablity doctrines
adopted by many courts and state legislatures which recognize certain
limited defenses  out  of  fairness to  those who could not have foreseen
or avoided the incident  and  are wholly  without  fault.^

        (7)  Impact on Other  Statutory Missions

             In general,  implementation  of § 311(1) appears to have
promoted cleanup  goals of the Clean  Water Act,  at least for the claims
which have been rendered.  A brief survey of  the  facts In each case
decided to date indicates that there have probably been few, if any,
                                 -90-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section  III
 unwarranted  recoveries.   Persons  who  fail  to  take  reasonable  pre-
 cautions  against  a  spill  usually  do not  recover  in the  Court  of
 Claims.185

             It  is possible, on  the other hand,  that  vigorous  defense
 by Department of Justice  lawyers  in the  Court  of Claims, -combined  with
 the  long  delay  in resolution  (suits are  still  pending where claims
 were  filed as early as 1975)  has  served  as  a  disincentive  to  voluntary
 cleanup,  even when  it seems that  the  spiller  would qualify for compen-
 sation under §  311(1).

             It  has also been  suggested that third  parties  who are
 actually  responsible for  spills may benefit by § 311(i), because  the
 Innocent  spiller will not attempt to  recover  from  such  a person,  and
 the government, who is subrogated to  the spiller1s rights  in  such  a
 situation, may  forego further action  because  of  the  time and  resource
 commitment that is often  required in  identifying the responsible  party
 and proving  the case*

             Finally, It has been  suggested  that  encouragement of
 voluntary cleanup may actually work against the  goals of CERCLA.
 Encouragement of such action might introduce  costs that will  burden
 the hazardous substance response  fund and  interfere  with the  alloca-
 tion of available resources to higher priority actions.  These
 objections,  however, were limited to  hazardous substance spills.

        (8) Other Congressional Policies

            No  significant conflicts  with other  congressional policies
 were identified.

 3.  Summary Assessment of § 311(1)

    a.  Is § 311(1) Appropriate and Needed?

        Information directly  supporting  the appropriateness and need
 for § 311(1) was obtained in  this study.  Representatives  of  industry
 and the Federal agencies have indicated  that  § 311(1) actually serves
 as encouragement to conduct voluntary cleanup  after  an  oil  spill  and
 to proceed with greater willingness to clean  up  when probable liabil-
 ity has been established by the government.   In  addition,  spokesper-
 sons for  the USCC indicated that  the  availability  of §  311(1) makes  it
 easier to persuade potentially responsible  persons to conduct cleanup,
 without being certain that they are actually  responsible,  since they
 will be eligible for an indemnity.  Assignment of  responsibility
 without a complete Investigation  is not  often  possible.  Such an
 option is particularly Important  because the USCG  may have  limited
 resources, or the USCG cleanup response  time  may be  unreasonably  long
when compared to the likelihood for environmental  damage and  the  more
 rapid response  that may be undertaken by private parties who  are
 closer to the Incident.  (A joint effort is often  appropriate.)
                                 -91-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
         Private  cleanup  may  also  be  more cost  effective  than  when
 undertaken  by  the  government  because of  private economic  efficiency
 incentives,  as well  as  because  of  the possibility that  continued delay
 will  allow  for a spill  to  spread  and make the  cleanup task more
 difficult.

         Although some potentially  negative impacts of §  311(1) have
 been  suggested,  no such  impacts were actually  documented.

         Whether  §  311(i) is  needed  for hazardous substance spills  is  a
 question that may  not be effectively addressed for two  reasons:  (1)
 there  have  been  no claims  under §  311(1) for  such spills  to date,  and
 (2) hazardous substance  spills  are covered under extensive new
 authority In CERCLA, which may  obviate further need for  §  311(1).

    b.   Potential Problem  Areas

         (1)  Administration in the Court  of Claims

             The  oftentimes long delay In resolving a claim, coupled
 with  the adversarial nature  of  the proceeding, may discourage volun-
 tary cleanup initiatives because of  the  actual difficulty  In  obtaining
 reimbursement of costs.  Alternatives have been suggested  In  H.R.
 85.187

         (2)  Availability of  Funds Under  § 311(k)

             The  lack of  funds under  § 311(k)  to finance  oil spill
 cleanup  on a large scale (e.g., similar  to the chemical  spill cleanup
 financed under CERCLA) may prevent complete cleanup and  other
 appropriate  remedial activity.

         (3)  Conflicting and Overlapping  Statutes

             All  four oil spill  statutes  contain different  liability
 standards, different financing  requirements, different administrative
.requirements, and other  Inconsistencies.   Although perhaps justified
 Individually when enacted, all  together  they  produce a complex web
 that Invites difficult and inconsistent  implementation.  These prob-
 lems are heightened by CERCLA, which Imposes a fifth set of liability
and reimbursement rules  for chemical  spills.

         (A)  Voluntary Cleanup of Chemical Spills by Innocent Parties

             CERCLA policies  prevent  large-scale financing  of cleanup
efforts  by dischargers,  including those  who are uncertain  of  their
 liability.   Section 311(1) has been  used  effectively In  such circum-
stances  to enable the USCC to persuade a  discharger to clean up
without  having to determine  liability, then pay later,  if  it  turns out
the discharger can assert  a defense  to liability.   CERCLA  policies may
                                 -92-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Section  III
not  permit  such  an approach; and  the agencies may  be  less willing  to
order  needed cleanup if there  is  reasonable doubt  regarding  the
discharger's liability.

            On a more fundamental level,  the  limited,  procurement
approach  to cleanup that EPA has  taken under  CERCLA suggests  that
there  is  little, if any, role  in  chemical spill  cleanup  for  voluntary,
unsupervised efforts.  This approach is strongly defended within EPA
and  may in actuality be the better approach for  chemical spills;
however,  insufficient experience  exists to make  such  a determination
at the present time.

A. The Applicability of § 311(1)  to Other EPA Programs

     a.  Introduction

        The following elements are Important  to  §  311(1):  (1) an
unanticipated spill, discharge or release of  a pollutant that is a
threat to the environment; (2) the possibility that effective Imme-
diate action may be taken by the  discharger to contain or remedy the
problem after the spill or release has occurred; (3)  greater  cost
savings or environmental benefit  if the discharger undertakes the  con-
tainment  or remedial action quickly; and  (4)  no  other  Incentive for
the  discharger to take such action voluntarily.

        If there exist other situations that  Include  the four
criteria, the question presented  is whether It is  reasonable  to
attempt to apply a mechanism such as § 311(1).   This  question depends
on whether the situation is already being addressed by a different
mechanism, whether that mechanism appears to  deal  adequately  with
situations of that type (or could be made to  do  so),  and whether a
§ 311 model could more profitably be utilized.

   .  b.  Evaluation of Other EPA Programs

        Sudden, unanticipated  pollution occurrences exist in  all of
the  pollution media subject to EPA jurisdiction.   Many of these are
hazardous and require some type of immediate  action.   In testimony on
Superfund, for example, Deputy Administrator  Barbara  Blum pointed  out
that as many as 1,800 spills a year are not regulated  under  § 311
because they go  into groundwater, the air, or onto land.  Moreover, as
many as 1,000 hazardous substance spills  that reach navigable waters
were not  subject to § 311 jurisdiction at the time because they
Involved  substances not yet designated under  § 311. °°

        This gap in authority  was one primary reason  for the  enactment
of CERCLA.  Its provisions cover  virtually every type  of hazardous
substance release for which application of a  § 311(1)  approach might
be appropriate.  These Include hazardous  substances designated under
§ 31l(b)(2)(A) of the Clean Water Act, hazardous wastes  listed under
                                 -93-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 § 3001 of the Resource Conservation and Recovery Act, hazardous pollu-
 tants listed under § 112 of the Clean Air Act, imminently hazardous
 chemical substances or mixtures which have been acted on pursuant to
 § 7 of the Toxic  Substances Control Act, and any other substance regu-
 lated pursuant to § 102 of  CERCLA.   The most significant coverage,
 however, Is provided under  § 104.   According to § 104(a)(l), whenever
 such a substance, or any other pollutant or contaminant which may pre-
 sent an Imminent  and substantial danger to the public heath or welfare
 Is  released or there Is a substantial threat of release into the
 environment,  the  President  is authorized to act in a manner consistent
 with the national contingency plan  to remove the substance and provide
 remedial action,  unless he  determines that removal and remedial action
 will be done  properly by a  responsible party.

         Under §  107,  the discharger Is liable for removal and remedial
 costs unless  he can prove that the  release and damages were caused
 solely by an  act  of God, an act of  war, or an act or omission of a
 third party.   In  such a case,  the statute is silent on the dischar-
 ger's prerogative to remove or conduct remedial action voluntarily.
 However,  § lll(a) provides  that the President may pay any claim for
 necessary response  costs Incurred by any person as a result of
 carrying out  the  national contingency plan so long as such costs are
 approved  under the  plan and certified by the responsible federal
 official.   Under  this provision,  EPA has Indicated that It will
 require prior approval  of private response efforts,"•"* and will
 strictly limit the  extent to which  CERCLA funds may be spent In that
 regard."0

         The  reasons for EPA's  position Include concerns over safety
 and  the chance of error (Inherent differences In the nature of oil and
 chemical  releases are noted),  but perhaps the most important concerns
 relate  to  the potential costs  Involved if private parties may conduct
 cleanup actions that  have not  been  preauthorlzed,  and the potential
 Interference  with EPA fund  allocation priorities.   In effect, EPA
 feels  that  the risks  of Increased environmental damage associated
 with  the  rejection  of a § 311(1) approach under CERCLA are outweighed
 by  the  need to ensure safety,  effective cleanup management, and
 control  over  fund allocations.

        At  this stage,  CERCLA  implementation has  not proceeded far
 enough  to  evaluate  the  successfulness of CERCLA policies as an alter-
 native  to  § 311(1).191   Until  such  time, it  would be Inappropriate to
 recommend  the  extension of  §  311(1)  to other EPA programs,  without an
 indication of  specific  circumstances in which cleanup efforts are
 falling  because there  is  no voluntary action by nonliable parties.  No
 such  Information  surfaced during this study.   Therefore,  no recommen-
dation  for extending  §  311(1)  to other EPA programs has been made.
 However,  in view  of  the  success  of  §  311(1)  in the area of  oil spills,
 it is recommended that  CERCLA  policies on this Issue be reconsidered
after sufficient  implementation  experience has been gained.
                                 -94-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
                       FOOTNOTES TO SECTION III

          following description and analysis draws on an extensive
 series of interviews with Involved parties at EPA, the Department of
 Justice,  industry and congressional staff.

     2P.L. 92-516, 86 Stat.  973.

     2a444 U.S.  51,  100 S. Ct.  318, 326 (1979) (citations omitted).

     •'The  Federal  Insecticide,  Fungicide,  and Rodenticlde Act of 1947,
 P.L.  80-104,  61  Stat. 163,  repealed and replaced the Insecticide Act
 of  1910,  P.L.  61-152, 36 Stat. 331.  Amendments to FIFRA were enacted
 in  1964 as  P.L.  88-305,  78  Scat.  190.

     4P.L. 94-140, P.L.  95-396, and P.L. 96-539.

     ^Allowing  farmers to use  their stocks is sometimes spoken of as
 "disposal by  use."  Spreading  the  pesticide out all over the country,
 rather than transporting and  then disposing of it all in one place,
 can  sometimes  reduce risks  to  human health and the environment.

     "See  Conner,  "Federal Indemnification for Losses Resulting from
 the  Suspension  of Hazardous Products — the Lessons of FIFRA," 32
 A.B.A. Admin. L.  Rev. 441 (1980).
     'Appendix A,  page  A-20.

     "Appendix A,  page  A-19.

     'Appendix A,  page  A-19.

     l°Appendlx A,  page A-18.
    HImminent  hazard  Is  not  a  statutory  basis  for  cancelling  a  pesti-
cide registration;  it  Is  the  basis  for  suspension.   The  language of
.§ 15 appears  to be  a drafting error.

    * This  provision was  Included by  the  Conference Committee  to
assure that Indemnification would be  denied  to  persons who  had not
produced a  pesticide in good  faith.   However,  the  language  goes  beyond
Inquiry Into  the claimant's knowledge of  the safety risks posed  by  the
pesticide.  It  seems to require an  investigation  Into whether  EPA
would conclude  that the risks are outweighed by the benfits of use,
because that  is the standard  for registration.  As  a practical matter,
It would be difficult  to  deny Indemnification  to  any producer  under
this standard because  the evidentiary requirements  are too  difficult.
Thus, It Is probably ineffective for  its  Intended  purpose of weeding
out those claiming  indemnification  in bad  faith.
                                 -95-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
      Supra  note 3 .

     *• The only  public records of these meetings are  three  revised cora
ralttee  prints of H.R. 4152.  Committee Print No. 2,  dated  June 22,
1971, contained a  very brief indemnity provision, while Committee
Print No. 3, dated July 13, 1971, contained a more detailed  indemnifi
cation  provision that eventually passed the House as H.R.  10729 in
November 1971.
           e.g-, testimony of American Farm Bureau Federation, Federal
Pesticide Control Act of 1971;  Hearings before the House Comm. on
Agriculture, 92d Cong., 1st Sess. 462 (1971); Dow Chemical Company,
id. at 302; Union Carbide Corporation, id.  at 332, 349-50; Sierra
Club, Federal Pesticide Control Act 1972:  Hearings Before the
Subcomm. on Agriculture Research and General Legislation of the
Senate Comm. on Agriculture and Forestry, 92d Cong., 2d Sess. 123, 127
(Part II) (Mar. 7-8, 1972); Environmental Defense Fund, id. at 156,
157; and the Public Interest Research Group, id. at 354-55.  It was
during the second day (February 23, 1971) of these hearings that the
indemnification Issue was raised in an exchange between Representative
Coodling (R.-Pa.) and J.P. Campbell, Undersecretary of Agriculture.
House Hearings at 67-68.

    16Coramittee of Conference, S. Rep. No. 92-1540, 92d Cong., 2d
Sess. (1972).

    1'The agreement was signed on May 7, 1979 after negotiations with
EPA's Office ot General Counsel and Chevron Chemical, the largest
manufacturer of Silvex products.

    18See 39 Fed. Reg. 14753 (Apr. 26, 1974) (emergency suspension),
EPA PR Notice 74-5 (Apr. 30, 1974), and 40 Fed. Reg. 3494 (Jan. 22,
1975) (cancellation).

    19For Aldrin/Dieldrin see 39 Fed. Reg. 37265-72 (Oct. 18, 1974)
(suspension), Environmental Defense Fund v. EPA, 510 F.2d 1292 (1975)
(suspension upheld but use of special rule ordered to be reconsid-
ered), and 40 Fed. Reg. 24232 (June 5, 1975) (status of existing
stocks).  For Heptachlor/Chlordane, see 39 Fed. Reg. 41298 (Nov. 26,
1974) (intent to cancel), 41 Fed. Reg. 7552 (Feb. 19, 1976) (intent to
suspend), 548 F.2d 998 (1976) (suspension upheld but special rule
ordered to be reconsidered), 43 Fed. Reg. 12372 (Mar. 4, 1978)
(cancellation allowing phase-out).

    20Interview on November 5, 1981 with Ralph Colleli, formerly EPA
Office of Pesticide Programs.

    ^Administrative hearing suspended for settlement negotiations.

    22House Hearings, supra note 15, at 349-50 (Mr. Wellman of Union
Carbide).
                                 -96-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
     ^Section 15 does not  specify the source of funds for paying
 indemnification claims.   In  response to a question from Senator
 Curtis,  David D. Dominick,  Assistant Administrator for Categorical
 Programs of  EPA, stated  that  EPA would "provide the Indemnification"
 under §  15.   There  was  no  discussion of the matter.  Senate Hearings,
 supra note 15,  at 93.   Anita  Johnson of the Public Interest Research
 Group argued in her testimony before the Senate Subcommittee that,
 "the  pending bill Is  abhorrent because it requires indemnities to be
 paid  from EPA funds."   Id.  at 354-55.

    2444 Fed.  Reg.  15874  (Mar. 15,  1979)

    ^Telephone conversation  on March 11, 1982 with Ray Krueger, EPA
 Office of Pesticides, Hazard  Evaluation.  As of March 11, 1982, four
 million  containers  of liquid  Silvex were still at  the collection
 points established  by the  registrants.  The disposal process will
 Involve  shipment of  the containers  of Silvex to the same waste facil-
 ity in Alabama  that was used  for the solid  pesticide.  EPA now has a
 contract with  the Alabama  facility  for disposal of the liquid.  The
 containers will be  opened and the liquid removed and incinerated, but
 it  is estimated that  this will not  occur prior to  September 1982.

    26117 Cong.  Rec.  40047  (1971) (e.g.,  remarks of Rep. Teague).

    27Interview on October 21,  1981  with Herb Harrison,  Chief  of
 Insecticide/Rodenticide Registration Branch.

    28Since  1972 EPA  has only denied registration  for five active
 ingredients  (used in  216 applications).    Four of  the five had already
 been  cancelled  when application for  the  new registration was made:
 DDT,  sodium  cyanide,  sodium fluoroacetate,  and heptachlor/chlordane.
 The fifth was a petition to use sodium arsenate in bottle tops.

    ^Telephone  conversation  on May  19,  1982  with  Edward Gray, EPA
 Acting Associate  General Counsel  for Pesticides.   (The Acting
Associate General Counsel for Pesticides  has  said  that this is so
 cleax to  all Involved that he has never  heard an argument to the
contrary).
          pesticide Industry Is so competitive  that  substitutes  are
constantly under study, even in the absence of  regulation.   The
National Research Council study Regulating Pesticides  estimates  the
economic life of a pesticide to be only about 10 years.
          example, the total impact of  the 2,4, 5T/Sllvex  suspensions
was estimated to be $89 million (nearly all attributed  to the  2,4,5T
uses).  The Economics Analysis Branch, Office of  Pesticide  Programs,
EPA Pesticide Cancellations/Suspensions:  A Survey of Economic  Impact,
March 1980.
                                 -97-

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Section  III
     32Supra  note 26 at 40053 on October 21,  1971  (Rep. Abernathy).

     33Id. at 40052 (Rep. Poage).

     •^Appendix A, page A-7.  See, e.g. , Mugler v. Kansas, 123 U.S. 623
(1887)  (elimination of a nuisance).
           e.g. , United States v. Pennsylvania Industrial Chemical
Corp.. 329 F. Supp. 1118 (W.D. Pa. 1971), rev'd & remanded. 461 F.2d
468  (3d Cir. 1972), modified, 411 U.S. 655  (1973) (discharge of
industrial waste without permit); and United States v. Articles of
Drug. . . Hormonin, 498 F. Supp. 424 (D.N.J. 1980) ("new drug"
required registration despite previous FDA  letter Indicating other-
wise).  See also, Thompson, "Equitable Estoppel of the Government," 79
Colum. L. Rev.  551 (1979); Apnot, "Estoppel Against Government," 27
A.L.R. Fed. 702 (1976).

     36Supra note 26 at 40049-50 (Rep. Goodling and Rep. Kyi).

     37House Hearings, supra note 15 at 349-50 (Mr. Wellman of Union
Carbide Corp.).

     •^Appendix E, page E-ll et^ seq.

     39Id. at 11.
    ^"Product Regulation and Chemical Innovation,"  (The Conservation
Foundation, March 1980), Interview with Dr. Arnold Aspelln, Chief
Economic Analysis Branch, Office of Pesticide Programs.

    42117 Cong. Rec. 40052 (1971) (Rep. Andrews and Rep. Poage).

     3Four of the five (used in 216 applications) had already been
cancelled when application for the new registration was made:  DDT,
sodium cyanide, sodium fluoroacetate, and heptachlor/chlordane.  The
fifth was a petition to use sodium arsenate in bottle tops.

    44Supra note 42 at 40052-53 (Rep. Bergland).

    4 5ld± at 40046 (Rep. Evans).

    46Id. at 40050 (Rep. Obey).

      The Trts case is the only product ban Indemnf ication situation
in which Congress has supported compensation, and that action was
vetoed by the President.  The Senate has now passed a new bill.  See
Appendix A, page A-22.

    48Appendlx E, page E-5.
                                -98-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
     ^Section  5  of  the  Toxic  Substance  Control  Act  requires manufac-
 turers  of  chemicals  to  notify the  Agency  90 days  before beginning com-
 mercial  production  of a new chemical.   If the Agency has concerns
 about a  new  chemical, It  can  order the  manufacturer to do specific
 tests though this happens rarely.

     Section  A  established an  Interagency  Testing  Committee that recom-
 mends to the Administrator which existing chemicals should be given
 priority consideration  for testing.  The  Administrator has 12 months
 to  respond to  the recommendations  by inflating  a  rulemaking or
 publishing in  the Federal Register a reason why It  will not be
 initiated.

     Section  8  contains  authority for several kinds  of recordkeeplng
 and  reporting  requirements.   The most important is  the Inventory
 established  by 8(b).  Until this section  was Implemented,  there had
 been no comprehensive knowledge of  what chemicals were being produced
 in  the United  States.   It  now provides  the  baseline for determining
 what chemicals are "new."  In addition, there is  a  mandatory duty to
 report to  the  Administrator "any information which  reasonably supports
 the  conclusion that such  substance  or mixture presents a substantial
 risk of  Injury to health  or the environment" under  § 8(e).

    Sections 6 and 7 provide  authority  to regulate  existing chemicals
 when there is  a  reasonable basis to conclude that they provide an
 unreasonable risk of Injury to human health or  the  environment.  The
 Administrator  is required  to  chose  the  least burdensome requirement
 that will adequately protect  against the  risk.  The economic con-
 sequences of the regulation are to  be taken Into  account,  as are the
 possibilities  of regulating under  another statute.   In fact, § 9
 requires the Administrator to  use  other EPA authorities to protect
 against the  risk unless it is  in public interest  to use TSCA.   If the
 risk may be  reduced to  a  sufficient extent  by action taken under a
 Federal law  administered  by another agency,  the Administrator  is
 required to  give the other agency an opportunity  to act,  before taking
action under TSCA.

    50TSCA § 6(d)(2) provides  for  immediately effective proposed
 rules, but If  the rule  proposes a  total ban,  it must be proceeded by a
court order  under § 7.  Thus,  the  only way  to immediately  ban  a chemi-
cal under TSCA is to go to court.

    ^Appendix A, at page A-22.

            page 134.

    5333 U.S.C. §§ 1251  et seq.

           97-117 (Dec.  29, 1981).
                                 -99-

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                            Section  III
           technology  Is defined,  In part,  In  terras of  its ability  to
produce:

    •   reduced  life-cycle costs of treatment facilities;
    •   reduced  primary energy requirements  for treatment; or
    •   improved environmental quality

as compared to  conventional technology*  U.S.  Environmental Protection
Agency, Innovative and Alternative Assessment Manual, (EPA
430/9-78-009] (1980).

    56The Clean Water Act § 202(a)(l), as amended by P.L. 97-117, con-
tains the new 55% limitation.

    ^information regarding the intent of the Conference Committee  in
including this  section is found in the House debates on the Conference
Report (the Senate debates do not mention § 202(a)(3)).  Rep. Roberts
explained the Committee's action:

                   In recognition of the risks involved In
              encouraging this departure from buslness-as-
              usual [as evidenced by the provisions encour-
              aging development and deployment of innovative
              and alternative technology],  the conferees
              adopted another amendment authorizing grants
              to cover the total cost of modifying or even
              replacing systems that do not perform as
              Intended and result in capital or operating
              and maintenance costs significantly higher
              than anticipated.  This, in effect, constitu-
              tes an insurance policy.
                   Innovative technology, as referred to in
              the conference report, means new and promising
              technology which has not been fully proven
              under the circumstances of this contemplated
              use. ... It would fall between the extremes
              of unproven technology, and the old conven-
              tional methods which have been duplicated and
              repeated endlessly in this country.  We think
              the key lies in the recognition and acceptance
              of a certain element of risk, which Is why we
              provide for the Federal Government to assume
              100 percent of the costs of modifying or
              replacing systems which fall to perform as
              intended*  These risks are deemed acceptable
              in light of the potential benefits in terms of
              environmental enhancement, lower capital or
                                 -100-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
              maintenance costs, and  reclamation, recycling
              and use of water which  Is becoming
              increasingly costly  to  provide.

3 A Legislative History of the Clean  Water Act of 1977, A Continuation
of the Federal Water Pollution Control Act 299, (emphasis added 307-08
(1978) (hereinafter cited as "CWA  Legislative History").  Later in  the
debate, Rep. Cleveland emphasized  the insurance nature of the
provision:

                   However, because we encourage Innovation
              and because we recognize there is risk, new
              subsection 202(a)(3) provides for payment of
              all of the costs of  modification or replace-
              ment of facilities which do not meet design
              performance specification.  This provision, an
              Insurance policy, recognizes there will be
              risks where technology  is pushed ahead.

3 CWA Legislative History 299, 385 (1978).

    58*0 C.F.R. § 35.2032(c), 47 Fed. Reg. 20462 (May 12, 1982).

    ^Telephone conversation on December 7, 1982 with Richard Thomas,
EPA Office of Water Program Operations, Municipal Technology Branch.

    60Section 202(a)(3) was not present in either S. 1952 or H.R. 3199
as originally passed by each House of Congress.  The indemnification
provision enacted into law was added by the Conference Committee:

              Additionally, the Administrator is authorized
              to make a grant to fund all costs of modifica-
              tion or replacement  of  facilities constructed
              with such a grant if they fail to meet design
              performance specifications, unless this
              failure is attributable to negligence, and has
              significantly increased capital or operating
              and maintenance expenditures.

H.R.  Rep. No. 95-830 at 55, 95th Cong., 1st Sess., reprinted in, 3 CWA
Legislative History 185, 239 (1978).

    61-Supra note 57.

    ^Concern for the encouragement of Innovation was very evident  in
the Senate Report on S. 3199:

                   More than any other issue concerning the
              construction grant program the committee
              hearings focused on  the need to encourage
                                 -101-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Section  III
              alternative  and  innovative  systems.   The  prob-
              lems  of  small  communities coping  with expen-
              sive  capital-intensive  waste  treatment  systems
              and the  wastefulness  of discharging  valuable
              nutrient  resources  to the Nation's waters  were
              stressed  throughout the country*  The need  for
              new Industrial processes which  produce  no
              waste was emphasized*

S. Rep. No. 95-370 at  5, 95th  Cong.,  1st  Sess., reprinted in, 4 CWA
Legislative History.

            note 57.

    6ASupra note 58.

    65Supra note 54.

    6643 Fed. Reg. 44049,  40 C.F.R. § 35.908(c).   The proposed new
regulations were published November 6, 1981.  45 Fed. Reg.  55220, pro-
posed 40 C.F.R. § 35.2032.  The 1978  regulations provided:

              (c) Modification or replacement of innovative
         and alternative projects.  The Regional Administra-
         tor may award  grant assistance to  fund 100 percent
         of the eligible costs of the modification or
         replacement of any treatment works constructed with
         85-percent grant  assistance  If:

              (1) He determines that:

              (1) The  facilities have not met design  perfor-
         mance specifications  (unless such  failure is due to
         any person's  negligence);

              (ii) Correction  of the  failure  requires signi-
         ficantly increased capital or operating and  main-
         tenance expenditures; and

              (lii) Such failure has  occurred within  the
         2-year period  following final inspection;  and

              (2) The  replacement or  modification  project is
         on the fundable portion of the State's priority
         list.

    ^Figures provided by  Richard Thomas, supra note  59.
       n FY 1980, the Construction Grants appropriation was $3.4
billion.
                                 -102-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Section  III
    69Supra note 54.

    7(^In addition,  there may be cost savings  relative  to conventional
technologies  in the operation or maintenance  of  the  plant.
    7233 U.S.C §§  1254 and 1255.

    7 telephone conversation on March 23, 1982 with William Cawley,
Deputy Director, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Industrial
Environmental Research Laboratory.
         U.S.C. § 1254 provides the authorization of the grants.

    77Telephone conversation on January 25, 1982 with Mike Maxwell,
Chief, Emission and Effluent Technology Branch, U.S Environmental
Protection Agency, Industrial Environmental Research Laboratory.

    ^Telephone conversation on February 1, 1982 with Malcolm P.
Huneycutt, Contracting Officer, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency,
Contract and Management Division (Research Triangle Park).

    79The mechanism providing for this insurance Is found in Clause 42
of the standard EPA contract which provides:

         (a)  The Contractor shall procure and maintain such
         Insurance as is required by law or regulation,
         including that required by Subpart 1-10.5 of the
         Federal Procurement Regulations as of the date of
         execution of this contract, and such insurance as
         the Contracting Officer prescribes by written
         direction.

         (b)  At a minimum, the Contractor shall procure and
         maintain the following types and amounts of insur-
         ance:

              (1)  Workmen's compensation and occupational
              disease insurance in amounts sufficient to
              satisfy State law;

              (2)  Employer's liability insurance, where
              available;

              (3)  Public liability insurance, on the com-
              prehensive form of policy, in the amount of
                                 -103-

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                            Section  III
               $200,000 per claimant and $500,000 per
               incident;

               (4)  When aircraft are used  In  the performance
               of the contract, aircraft public and passenger
               liability Insurance, in such form, in such
               amounts, and for such periods of time as  the
               Contracting Officer may require or approve;

               (5)  When vessels are used in the performance
               of the contract, vessel collision liability
               and protection and Indemnity liability Insur-
               ance, in such form, in such amounts, and  for
               such periods of time as the Contracting
               Officer may require or approve.

         (c)   With respect to any insurance policy all or
         part  of the premiums of which the Contractor
         proposes to treat as a direct cost under this
         contract, and with respect to any proposed
         qualified program of self-Insurance, the written
         approval of the Contracting Officer shall be
         obtained prior to any claim for payment therefor.
         The Contractor shall be reimbursed for the protion
         allocable to this contract.

         (d)   The term of any other insurance policy held by
         the Contractor shall be submitted to the Contract-
         Ing Officer for review and/or approval upon request
         of the Contracting Officer.

(Emphasis added.)

    8°A2 U.S.C. § 7413.

    81Federal  clean air legislation dates back to 1955.  See Act of
July 14, 1955, 69 Stat. 322.   Numerous amendments have occurred since.
The most significant, however, were the 1970 and 1977 amendments.
Pub. L. 91-604, 84 Stat. 1676 (December 31, 1970); and Pub- L. 95-95,
91 Stat. 712 (Nov. 16,  1977).  See, e.g., "The Clean Air Act Amendment
of 1977:  A Selective Legislative Analysis" 13 Land & Water L. Rev.
747 (1978); "Enforcement and  Litigation Under the Clean Air Act
Amendments of  1977," 12 Natural Resources Lawyer 435 (1979); "Clean
Air Act Amendments of 1977,"  19 Natural Resources J. 475 (1979).

           e.g., "Enforcement and Litigation under the Clean Air Act
Amendments of  1977," 12 Natural Resources Lawyer 435, 482-87 (1979).

    83As first offered  by Representative Satterfield (D. Va.), it pro-
vided that a court could make an award whenever it found the action
                                 -104-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 "unwarranted"  or  determined  that  such an award was "appropriate."
 Although Satterf ield' s  amendment  was rejected, the committee passed  a
 similar  amendment (and  one  identical to the provision ultimately
 enacted) offered  by  Representative Eckhardt (D.  Tex.)i  and  amended  by
 Representative Dlngell  (D. Mich.), which restricted the award to
 actions  found  to  be  "unreasonable."  A separate amendment  offered  by
 Representative Frey  (R.  Fla.)  to  provide an award only  to  a
 "prevailing" party was  also  rejected in Committee.  Minutes of the
 House  Committee on Interstate  and Foreign Commerce (Full Committee
 Mark-up  Session,  Clean  Air Act Amendments of 1976), 94th Cong.,  2d
 Sess.  (March 19,  1976).

    84H.R.  Rep. No.  94-1175  at 277, 94th Cong.,_2d Sess.,  reprinted  In
 7 CAA  Legislative History 6547, 6826 (1978).
                                    o
    85S.  Rep.  No. 95-127 at  99-100, 95th Cong.,  1st Sess.,  reprinted
 ^n 3 CAA Legislative History 1371,  1473-74 (1978).
            the amendment  to  §  113(b) was  under  consideration,  a
separate, parallel provision  involving  suits  against  the  Administrator
was also under consideration.   The  1970 Amendments  had  provided In
§ 304(d) for an award of attorneys'  fees In citizen suits,  whenever
the court determined that  such  an award was "appropriate."  The pur-
pose of this provision was both to  encourage  legitimate public  Inter-
est suits (against industry or  the  agency) and to discourage  harassing
suits by allowing for costs to  be imposed  against the plaintiff in
such circumstances.  S. Rep.  No. 91-1196 at 38,  91st Cong., 2d  Sess.,
reprinted in 1 CAA Legislative  History  397, 438  (1974).

    Prior to the 1977 Amendments interest  was expressed by  industry
and environmental organizations in  extending  this provision to  suits
brought for the purpose of reviewing agency rulemaking, and other
similar actions, under § 307  of the  Act.   As  with § 304,  it was
argued, such suits would serve  to promote  the public  Interest by
serving as a check against unreasonable rulemaking. This ultimately
resulted in the enactment  of  §  307(f) which allows  for  a  similar
award, again whenever a court determines that it is "appropriate;" and
the stated purposes are essentially  the same  as  in  § 304:   "to  prevent
harassment of innocent parties," and to "reimburse  citizens who seek
to enforce the law." S. Rep.  No. 94-717 at 82-3, 94th Cong.,  2d Sess.,
reprinted in 6 CAA Legislative  History  4701,  4783-84 (1978).

    87See Alyeska Pipeline Co., v. Wilderness Society,  421  U.S. 240
(1975);  "Awards of Attorneys' Fees  by the  Federal Courts  (Part  I)," 6
ALI-ABA Course Materials J. 95  (1982).
           e.g. E. Larson, Federal Court Awards of Attorney's Fees
257, n. 5 and Appendix C (1981).
                                 -105-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
     9°See,  e.g.,  Clean Water Act  §  505(d);  Toxic  Substances  Control
 Act § 20;  Safe Drinking Water Act §  1449(d);  Noise Control Act
 § 12(d);  Resource Conservation and  Recovery Act § 7002(e).  The
 Federal Insecticide,  Fungicide, and  Rodenticlde Act;  and  the Compre-
 hensive Environmental Response, Compensation,  and Liability  Act of
 1980 do not contain a similar provision.

     91The  "Equal  Access to  Justice  Act"  appears at Title  II  of  the
 "Small Business Export Expansion  Act of  1980."  Pub.  L. 96-481; 94
 Stat. 2321.   Its  provisions are codified  at 5  U.S.C.  §  504 and  28
 U.S.C. §  2412.  The effective date was October 1,  1981.

     92H.R.  Rep. No.  96-1418,  96th Cong., 2d  Sess., reprinted in 1980
 U.S.  Code Cong. & Ad.  News  4984-89.

     93See H.R.  Rep. No.  94-1175 at 277; Minutes of the House Committee
 on  Interstate  and Foreign Commerce,  March 18,  1976; S.  Rep. No.
 94-717 at 82-3; Transcripts of the Senate Committee on Environment and
 Public Works,  March 16,  1977.  See Sierra Club v.  Gorsuch. 16 E.R.C.
 2113,  2120  (D.C.  Clr.  1982) (Sierra  Club awarded  fees but  did not pre-
 vail  under  §  307(f) of the  Clean  Air Act).
    94
      See discussion of S  113(b), supra at 86.
          discussion of cases on point  in 6 AL1-ABA Course Materials
J_._ 95  (1982).  This policy  is also provided in Canon 7-4 of  the Code
of Professional Responsibilities for Attorneys:

              The advocate  may urge any permissible con-
              struction of  law favorable to his client  .  .  .
              his conduct is within the bounds of  law,  and
              therefore permissible, if the position taken
              is supported  by any good  faith argument  for an
              extension, modification, or reversal of  the
              law.  However, a lawyer is not justified  in
              asserting a frivolous claim.

    9630 U.S.C. § 425(e).

    97 See 43 C.F.R. § 4.1294; Colloquy between Seiberllng and Udall,
_ Cong. Rec. H3826, April  29, 1977; H. R. Rep. No. 95-218 at 90, 95th
Cong., 1st Sess.

    98Interview on October  13, 1981 with Mark Squlllace, Office of  the
Solicitor, Department of Interior.

    9943 C.F.R. §§ 4.1294(c) and (d).  See also 43 Fed. Reg. 34385-86
(Aug. 3, 1978); H.R. Rep. No. 95-218 at 311, 95th Cong. 1st Sess.

    100Supra note 91.
                                 -106-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
     101H.R.  Rep.  No.  96-1418,  96th Cong.,  2d Sess., reprinted in 1980
 !U..S. Code Cong.  & Ad. News 4984,  4994.
            rejected standard  had  been offered by the Department of
 Justice as a compromise to the standard ultimately enacted*  Depart-
 ment  opposition had been particularly strong.  In a statement before
 the House Committee on Small  Business (May 1, 1980), Alice Daniel,
 Assistant Attorney General, Civil  Division,  argued that such legisla-
 tion  could cost taxpayers well over 100 million dollars a year, that
 it  would be overreaching in its disruption of government enforcement,
 that  it would be more  efficient to eliminate bad regulations and
 improve the regulatory process than to establish disincentives to
 enforcement;  and that  establishing a presumption against the reason-
 ableness of a regulatory action departed from a long valid tradition
 without justifiable cause.

    In  its report on H.R.  6429 (S. 265), the House Committee on Small
 Business indicated that placing the burden on a prevailing party to
 challenge the reasonableness  of the underlying agency action would be
 deterrent to  small business,  and would thwart Congress1 interest in
 ensuring that such rights  be  vindicated.  The Report goes on to note:

               The standard and burden of proof in S. 265
               represents an acceptable middle ground between
               an automatic award of fees and the restric-
               tive standard proposed by the  Department of
               Justice.   It presses the agency to address the
               problem  of abusive and harassing regulatory
               practices.  It  is Intended to  caution agencies
               to carefully evaluate their case and not to
               pursue those which are weak or tenuous.  At
               the same  time,  the language of the section
               protects  the government when its case, though
               not prevailing,  has  a reasonable basis in law
               and fact.   Furthermore,  it provides a safety
               valve where  unusual  circumstances dictate that
               the government  is advancing in good faith a
               credible,  though novel,  rule of law.

H.R. Rep.  No.  96-1418 at 13-14, 96th Cong. 2d Sess., reprinted in
1980 U.S.  Code  Cong. &  Ad. News 4984,  4993.

    103Interview on January 27, 1982 with Don Stevers, Department of
Justice.
             involving the Apache Powder case  were  derived  primarily  in
the following interviews:  interview with Barbara Brandon,  former
Attorney, Department of Justice, January, 1982;  interview with Craig
                                 -107-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 Litman,  Attorney,  EPA Region  IX,  January,  1982;  Interview with  Amy
 Coy,  Counsel  for  Apache  Powder  from  Evans,  Kitchel  and  Jenckes,
 Phoenix,  Arizona,  Fehruary  3,  1982.

     lo&Letter to  Marvin  B.  Durnlng,  Esquire,  Assistant  Administrator
 for  Enforcement,  EPA,  from  James  W.   Moorman,  Assistant Attorney
 General,  Lands  and  Natural  Resources Division,  Department of  Justice
 (May  26,  1978); "Region  IX  Position  on  the  Confession of Error  by  the
 Department  of Justice  In U.S. v.  Apache  Powder  Co.,  Civ. No.  78-058,
 In the United States  District Court  for  the District of Arizona,"
 unpublished EPA document.

        __,>ra  note  103.

      ""interview with  Sharon Green,  General Accounting  Office,  January
 27,  1982.  The  Judgment  Fund utilized for § 113(b)  is the same  fund
 from  which Silvex  indemnification claims under  §  15  of  the Federal
 Insecticide,  Fungicide,  and Rodenticlde  Act have  been paid.   See
 discussion supra at page 33.
           Coy supra note 105.

    ^-Barbara Brandon supra note 105.  A  recent estimate of  the
average award for judicial proceedings generally, excluding tax cases,
was approximately $16,000 for attorney fees and $2,000 for other
costs.  Congressional Budget Office, "Cost Estimate  for S.265, the
Equal Access to Justice Act," July 18, 1979, reprinted in Sen. Rep.
No. 96-253, 96th Cong., 1st Sess., at 10-12.
       See Environmental Protection Agency, "Justification of
Appropriation Estimates for Committee on Appropriation, Fiscal Year
1983" A-106-117.

           Coy supra note 105.
    ll5Intervlew with Edward Reich, Director, Division of Stationary
Source Enforcement, Environmental Protection Agency on September 22,
1981.

    116Amy Coy supra note 105.
           internal concurrence requirements for all judicial actions
are rigorous.  See "Draft Memorandum from EPA Administrator Anne M.
Gorsuch on General Operating Procedures for Civil Enforcement
Program," reprinted in BNA Environmental Reporter, Current Develop-
ments (May 21, 1982) at 78-85.  In addition, Department of Justice
                                 -108-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Section III
 review is  even  more  demanding.   Interviews  with Jeffrey  Miller  of
 Bergson,  Borkland, Margolis  and  Adler  (Former Acting  Assistant
 Administrator for Enforcement, Environmental  Protection  Agency)
 (December,  1981) and Angus Mac Beth  of  Bergson,  Borkland,  Margolis  and
 Adler  (Former Assistant  Attorney General, Lands and Natural  Resources
 Division,  Department of  Justice  (December,  1981).  See also  "Memo-
 randum of  Understanding  on Civil Enforcement  Between  the Justice
 Department  and  the Environmental Protection Agency" (June 13, 1977),
 reprinted  in BNA Environment  Reporter,  Federal  Laws 41:2401;
 Memorandum  to Regional Administrators  from  Kathleen Bennett  (December
 29,  1981)  (emphasizes  that enforcement  should be focused  on  signifi-
 cant violators  that have been pre-selected  with state assistance and
 that states should be  encouraged to take  the  lead).

     118Infra Section IV,  notes 73-76.   Most complaints related  to  the
 underlying  regulations and EPA interpretations  of  congressional
 policy.  However, Attorney George Freeman of  Hunton and  Williams,  a
 Richmond, Virginia law firm  that actively represents  industrial and
 electric power  facilities In  proceedings  involving EPA regulations,
 raised  several  complaints relating  to EPA negotiating policies  and the
 use  of  civil penalty authority.   Senate Oversight  Hearings,  June 4,
 1981,  part  2, No. 97-H12, 97th Cong., 1st Sess.  at 479-482.

             supra note  115;  Miller supra note  117.

             Section IV,  notes 73-76.   Other  sources  consulted  include
 BNA Environment Reporter, Cases  (vols.  14-16  through  May  21, 1982),
 Current Developments (May 1,  1979 - May 21, 1982).

    121Supra note 117.

    122Id.

    123Supra notes 112 and 117.
       Reich supra note 115.  Miller supra note  117.   Interview with
Richard Wilson, Environmental Protection Agency,  September,  1981.
         provision in the Senate version of  the  "Equal Access  to
Justice Act" would have required payment from  previously  appropriated
funds and would not have allowed an appropriation  specifically for  the
purpose of an attorney fees award.  See S. 265 §§  3(d) and 4(d)(4),
96th Cong. 1st Sess.  However, this requirement  was  not  Included  in
final legislation.
           discussion supra at 67.

    12733 U.S.C. § 1321.
             up of hazardous substance spills, but not  oil,  is  now
covered primarily by the Comprehensive Environmental  Response,  Compen-
sation and Liability Act of 1980.  kl U.S.C. §§  9601  et  seq.
                                -109-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
     129Executive  Orders  11735 (August 3,  1973)  and 12316 (August 14,
 1981)  delegate  presidential  authorities and  responsibilities  for
 carrying out  the  provisions  of  §  311  and  CERCLA.   Executive Order
 12316,  § 1,  provides  that  the National Response Team under the
 National Contingency  Plan  will  Include representatives of the
 Department of State,  Department of  Defense,  Department of Justice,
 Department of the Interior,  Department of Agriculture, Department of
 Labor,  Department of  Health  and Human Services, Department of Energy,
 Environmental Protection Agency,  Federal  Emergency Management Agency
 and  United States Coast  Guard.  Other specific  agencies with  important
 roles  under § 311 include  the Public  Health  Service and the Federal
 Maritime Commission.
           §  311 defenses are very  strictly  construed  and  apply  only
 if  the  discharger has  had no part at  all  in  causing  the  discharge.
 See U.S. v. Bear Marine Services. 16  E.R.C.  1953,  1956,  n.  3  (E.D.  La.
 1980);  Sabine Towing & Transportation Co., Inc. v. United  States,  16
 E.R.C.  2081 (U.S. Ct.  Cl. 1981); United States v.  LeBeouf  Brothers
 Touring Co.. 621 F.2d  787, rehearing  den.. 629 F.2d  1350 (5th Cir.
 1980),  cert, den.. 452 U.S. 906  (1981).

    13133 U'S.C. S 1321(1) (Supp. 1981).
           Report of the Senate Committee on Public Works  accompanying
S.7, No7~9~l-351 (August 7, 1969) 91st Cong., 1st  Sess.,  at  17-19.
Note, that the Court of Claims recently rejected  an argument  that  the
remedial purpose of § 311(i) required a permissive reading  of  an
exception listed in § 3ll(i)(l).  Sabine Towing & Transportation Co.,
Inc. v. United States, supra at 2084.

    *33See discussion infra at 90.  It has also been argued that cost
savings in cleanup is an Important factor.  Early response  may avoid
the cost of more extensive cleanup.  But also, it is a common  percep-
tion in the private sector that a profit oriented enterprise will
attain more effective cost control.  In addition, federal  procurement
requirements may result In additional costs when  the USCG or EPA
undertakes cleanup.  On the other hand, it is possible that §  311(1)
would encourage more extensive cleanup costs by a private  party than
the government would be willing to incur.  See discussion  infra at 91.

    13;>P.L. 91-224, 84 Stat. 91.  See Sabine Towing & Transportation
Co., Inc. v. United States, supra at 2082.

    135P.L. 92-500, 86 Stat. 862.
          . 95-576.  Regulations listing hazardous substances were
promulgated on March 13, 1978 at 43 Fed. Reg. 10479 (40 C.F.R. §  116);
regulations establishing reportable quantities were promulgated August
29, 1979 at 44 Fed. Reg. 50776 (40 C.F.R. § 117).
                                -110-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
     13742  U-S'C.  §§  9601  et  seq.;  P.L.  96-510;  94  Stat.  2767.

     *™CERCLA  does noc  necessarily preempt  the  regulation of  hazardous
 substances  under  § 311.   See CERCLA §  304(c).   Except  for the  transfer
 of  funds provided in CERCLA  § 304(b),  EPA and  the  USCG have agreed  to
 utilize the Hazardous Substance  Response  Fund  under CERCLA rather than
 the  §  311(k) fund for hazardous  substance response because of  the
 additional  funds  available under CERCLA.  See  EPA-USCG "Reimburseable
 Agreement  for  Funds  Expended by  311(k)  Pollution Fund  on Behalf  of
 Section 104 of  CERCLA," signed by  Michael B. Cook, EPA (April  24,
 1981), and  by  W.E. Caldwell,  USCG  (April  20, 1981). Nevertheless,  it
 is arguable that  claims under §  311(1)  may  still be made for  the 297
 designated  substances under  § 311.   See infra,  note 170. .

     139S. 7, §  12(j). See 1970 U.S.  Code  Cong.  & Admin.  News at  2720.

            at  2726.
           model appears  in an oil  Industry  sponsored  non-statutory
solution to public concerns involving  the  increasing frequency  of  oil
spills.  Tanker owners devised an international  voluntary  plan
entitled "Tanker Owners Voluntary Agreement  Concerning Liability for
Oil Pollution (TOVALOP)." Under this plan, participating tanker owners
would agree to reimburse  the government for  cleanup costs  up  to a
stated maximum in the case of negligent spills and would expect reim-
bursement for cleanup expenses for  non-negligent  spills.

    Another model exists  In the 1969 Convention  of Civil Liability for
Oil Pollution Damage, Article V, 8, reprinted in  BNA:  International
Environment Reporter, Reference File,  Vol. 1, 21:1501.  Although an
individual ship owner Is  responsible for constituting  the  fund  under
this convention, Article V, 8 treats voluntary cleanup expenses
Incurred by the owner with equal rank  to other claims  against the
fund.  (As of July 1980 the United  States  was not a party  to  the
Convention.)  See also, the 1971 Convention  on the Establishment of an
International Fund for Compensation for Oil  Pollution  Damage,
reprinted in BNA:  International Environment Reporter, Reference File,
Vo. 1, 21:1701, which established an oil spill damage  compensation
fund financed by contributions of member nations.  Article 4  provides
indemnification for voluntary cleanup  in certain  circumstances.  (As
of September 1977 the United States was a  party  to this Convention.)
            for the provision Is mentioned only once — by  the
American Waterways Operators, Inc.

    143S_ee_, for example, Hearing on H.R. 85, No. 96-26, 96th Cong.  1st
Sess. at 194 (testimony of Swep Davis) September 26, 1979;  Committee
Report on H.R. No. 96-172, 96th Cong. 1st Sess., reprinted  in 1980
U.S. Code Cong. & Admin. News at 6184-6186 (legislative history  to
CERCLA); Regulations on Determination of Reportable Quantities for
                                 -111-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Section  III
 Hazardous  Substances,  Preamble,  44  Fed. Reg.  50776  (August  29,  1979);
 Memorandum from  Christopher  J. Capper  and  William A.  Sullivan,  Jr.  to
 Regional Administrators  (February 23,  1982) at  5, 9;  EP.\  pamphlet,
 "EPA's  Emergency Response  Program"  (HW-3)  (April, 1982);  it  is  also  an
 implicit facet of EPA's  recently published "Guidelines  for  Using  the
 Imminent Hazard,  Enforcement and Emergency Response Authorities of
 Superfund  and Other Statutes," 47 Fed. Reg. 20664 (May  13,  1982).

    l^Report of  the Senate  Committee  on Public Works accompanying
 S. 7 , supra at 17.
          U.S.C.  §§  1651 et seq.

    IA633 U.S.C. §§ 1501 et seq.

    U743 U.S.C. §§ 1801 et sag.
          U.S.C. §§ 9601 et seq.  There are numerous other  legal
authorities that may apply to the prevention and cleanup of oil and
hazardous substance spills.  See, e.g. , 40 C.F.R. Part 1510, Annex
VII.
           a brief comparison of the four oil spill  fund statutes,  see*
Musgrove, Lee, Reisch, Blodgett and Armltage, "Compensation and
Liability Legislation for Victims of Toxic Substance Pollution:  A
Comparison of Proposals," (September 16, 1979), reprinted in hearing
on H.R. 85, No.  96-26, 96th Cong. 1st Sess. (September 26, 1979) at
442-44.

    I500uter Continental Shelf Lands Act Amendments of 1978 (OCSLA)
§ 303(b)(l)(A); Deepwater Port Act of 1974 (DWPA) §  18(f)(5).

    151QCSLA S 303(b)(l)(B); DWPA § 18(f)(2).

    1 52Trans-Alaska Pipeline Authorization Act of 1973 (TAPAA)
§ 204(b).  See Alyeska Pipeline Service Co. v. U.S., 16 E.R.C. 1812
(U.S. Ct. Cl. 1981).

    153See TAPAA § 204(c).

    l54Proposed oil "Superfund" legislation In 1979 was justified In
part as a means of unifying a "patchwork of overlapping, inconsistent
Federal and State laws."  Letter to Hon. Thomas P. O'Neill, Jr. from
Brock Adams (Secretary of Transportation), March 20, 1979, forwarding
H.R. 29 to Congress, reprinted in House Hearings No. 96-16, March 13,
1979, at 105.

    155H.R. 85 was passed by the House In 1980, but not the Senate.
It was Introduced again In 1981 but was not acted on by the House or
the Senate.  It has not been relntroduced In 1982.   Interview with
                                 -112-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 Suznnne  Bolton,  Subcommittee  Staff,  May  25,  1982.   A more  recent  bill,
 JI..R.  5906,  currently  under  active  consideration,  would  amend  the  Outer
 Contenttal  Shelf Lands Act  to  impose  nn  overall  limit of $75  million
 on  the  liability of owners  and  operators for  damages and cleanup
 costs.   As  explained, this  would facilitate  the  insurability  of oil
 drilling  facilities.  Id.
              issues arising  in a  legislative  debate  on  the  oil  Super-
fund  legislation  include:

        •   the ability to minimize defenses to  liability;

        •   the need to impose stricter  penalties  to  help  prevent
            spills, as well as to  encourage prompt  mitigation  and
            cleanup efforts;

        •   the need for a larger  fund to  finance  cleanup  when respon-
            sible  parties cannot be Identified;

        •   the need for expanded  provisions relating  to consequential
            damages and damages incurred by third  parties;

        •   the need for state reimbursement and legislative
            preemption;

        •   the use of fees to finance the fund  (amount, to whom
            charged, how managed,  etc.); and

        •   limits on liability and defenses.
House Hearings No. 96-16 (March 13, 14, July 31, September  13,  1979);
No.  96-26 (September 26, 1979); No. 96-114 (June  19, August  17,
October 10, 11, 1979).  Most of these issues were  ultimately  addressed
under CERCLA, which grew out of the oil Superfund  legislative efforts
but ironically was enacted without oil spill coverage.

   • 157House Hearing No. 96-16, supra at 66-77.  Under §  102  the
Department of the Treasury would be responsible  for administering  the
fund, which would be financed by a fee charged to  refiners  and
export/import terminals.  Other aspects of the law would  be imple-
mented by the Department of Transporation, except  that private
insurance or claims adjustment organizations would be relied  on to
process claims.  A formal administrative review  procedure would apply
in the case of claims disputes, while federal cost recovery and
penalty collection proceedings would be handled  through the Department
of Justice.

    158See Congressional Quarterly, Almanac — 1980 at 584-93.
                                 -113-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
     ^'Hearings Before the Subcommittee on Transportation and Commerce
 of the House Committee on Interstate and Foreign Commerce on 11. R.
 4571,  H.R,  4566,  and H.R. 5290 (June 19, 1979), No. 96-1U (1980) at
 216-246.

     l60Section 7003 was thought to be Ineffective because of the dif-
 ficulty In  Identifying the responsible party,  the financial Inability
 of responsible parties to cover the costs of remedial action, the dif-
 ficulty in  sustaining the legal burden of demonstrating that the
 hazard is "imminent and substantial," and the  time lapse that occurs
 during trial*   Aside from the  problems of limited coverage, § 311 and
 the emergency  powers provision of  the Clean Water Act, § 504, were
 criticized  because  they contained  inadequate funds to allow for effec-
 tive action by EPA  — $35 million  under § 311,  and $10 million under
 §  504  compared to an estimated need of as much  as $6.1 billion to
 address Inactive and abandoned hazardous waste  dump sites alone.
 Similar procedural  and funding constraints were said to exist in other
 hazardous substance control  statutes, such as §§ 112 and 303 of the
 Clean  Air Act.  Id.

     161See  40  C.F.R.  § 300.25(d),  47 Fed. Reg.  31207 (July 16,  1982).
            types of  funding mechanisms  are  available  for preauthorized
expenses.   A cooperative agreement  may  be established with states anfl
political subdivisions; and contracts may be  given to private parties.
If an emergency exists up  to $2,500 may be  made  available to persons
not already on EPA's  preferred contractor list;  and up to $50,000 be
made available to  preferred contractors.  Interim Emergency Procure-
ment for Hazardous Substance Response Program (undated EPA document).
              factors were suggested  in discussions with  numerous state
and  federal agency staff involved  In the  implementation  of  CERCLA.

     16^Supra  notes 159, 161, and 163.  See also  "Guidelines for Using
the  Imminent  Hazard, Enforcement and Emergency response  Authorities of
Superfund and Other Statutes," 47  Fed. Reg.  20664 (May 13,  1982);
House Hearing on "Implementation of  the Comprehensive Environmental
Response, Compensation, and Liability Act of 1981" No. 97-H31,  97th
Cong. 1st Sess. (July 8, 1981), statement of Congressman Florlo, at
5-6.

     l^Intervlew uith Swep Davis,  Environmental  Testing  Corporation
(Former Associate Assistant Administrator for Water  and  Waste
Management, EPA), May 3, 1982.
       S«£ House Hearings, No. 97-H31, supra note  164.

    ^^Information derived from a review of case files  In  the U.S.
Court of Claims.  ICF Draft Memorandum, "Cost Associated with §  311(1)
of the Clean Water Act," March 8, 1982 for EPA's Office of Toxic
Substances, Regulatory Impacts Branch.
                                -114-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Section  III
          _  e . g . , House Hearings on Coast Guard Authorization,  F.Y.
1982  (H7R7 2559) and Oversight, March  16, 1981, H.  Rep.  No. 97-2, 97th
Cong.  1st Sess., 251, 298, 302.  It should  be  noted  that  such  respon-
sibilities exist under DCS LA and DWPA.  However,  Implementation
experience is too limited to allow for evaluation  at  this stage.

    I70lnterviews with:  Commander George Brown,  USCG,  12th District
and Commander Skip Omstead, USCG, llth District, January  27, 1982.

    l71See_, e.g.. Quarles Petroleum Co. v.  United  States,  551  F.2d
1201,  1204 (U.S. Ct. Cl. 1977) (sets out elements  of  §  311(1)  claim).

    172Interview with Commander Adams, USCG, March 22,  1982.
    175In 1979 EPA estimated that from 700-1,200 chemical spills
occured each year which .would be subject to § 311 regulation.
Statement of Barbara Blum, Deputy Administrator, House Hearings on
H.R. 4571, H.R. 4566, and H.R. 5290, No. 96-113, 96th Cong.  1st Sess
at 225.
           continued availability of a remedy under § 311(1) to a
discharger of contaminants covered under CERCLA depends on whether
§ 311(1) in a particular case is determined to be  In conflict with
CERCLA.  See CERCLA § 304(c).  Such an argument might be made in the
case of expenses not authorized as consistent with the national con-
tingency plan.  See CERCLA § lll(a)(2).  Note, however, that special
relief in such a situation might be available under CERCLA § lll(b).

    ^  Adams supra note 172.

    178See

    17940 C.F.R. part 112; 33 C.F.R. part 154.  Hazardous substance
spill prevention regulations do not exist and are  not included on the
most recent regulatory agenda.  See 47 Fed. Reg. 15702 (April 12,
1982).

    l80Section 311(b)(5) provides for up to $10,000 In fines and one
year of imprisonment for failure to report a discharge, and
§ 311(b)(6) requires an assessment by the USCG of  up to $5,000 as a
civil penalty for each offense and, alternatively, allows for EPA to
pursue in court penalties not exceeding $50,000 per discharge (or not
exceeding $250,000 If willful negligence or misconduct was involved).
In addtlon, § 311(j) allows for an administrative  penalty of up to
                                 -115-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section III
 $5,000  for  each violation of prevention,  containment and removal
 regulations •

     Section 103(a)  of  CERCLA provides  for up to $10,000 in fines  and
 one  year  of imprisonment  for notification violations, and $20,000 In
 fines and one  year  of  imprisonment  for record keeping violations*
 Failure to  comply with an abatement order under §  106 may result  in up
 to a $5,000 penalty for each day  of violation;  and under § 109 up to
 $10,000 per day may be assessed against a person who has failed to
 comply with financial  responsibility requirements  under § 108.  If a
 person  fails to conduct required  removal  or  remedial actions,  pursuant
 to § 107(c)(3)  he may  be  liable for punitive damages that amount  to
 three times the amount of costs incurred  by  the Hazardous Substance
 Response  Fund*
            was a  conclusion  of  the  First  Report  of  the  President's
Panel on Oil Spills.   Executive  Office  of  the  President,  Office  of
Science and Technology,  "The  Oil Spill  Problem,"  (undated publication)
at 4.
                  other  than  §  311(1)  already  exist,  including  fore-
knowledge  that defenses  to  liability are  very  narrowly  construed,
possible liability  for unreasonable costs  of cleanup  if undertaken  by
the government,  treble damages  (under  CERCLA § 107(c)), potential
state and  common  law  liability  and concerns over  public image.

           discussion supra at  83.

             however, that  the  Trans-Alaska Pipeline  Authorization  Act
of 1973, 43 U.S.C.  §§ 1651  et seq., does  not provide  an act of  God  or
third-party-negligence defense.  The legislative  history notes  that
stricter liability  standards  are warranted because  of the enormous
size of tankers expected  to transport  oil  from Alaska and the
increased  risk, therefore,  of high damages to  property  and natural
resources.  1973 U.S. Code  Cong. & Admin. News, at  2530.

    185See_, e.g., City of Pawtuckett v. United States,  211 Ct.  Cl.
324 (1976); Proctor Wholesale Co. v. United States. 215 Ct. Cl.  1049
(1978); Chicago, Milwaukee. St. Paul & Pacific Railroad Co. v.  United
States^ 575 F.2d 839  (U.S.  Ct.  Cl. 1978).

    l86See text and notes,  supra at 80.

           text and notes,  supra at 78.
    188Supra note 136.
    l89See 40 C.F.R. § 300.25(d), 47 Fed. Reg. 31207  (July 16, 1982).
           "Guidelines for Using the Imminent Hazard, Enforcement and
Emergency Response Authorities of Superfund and Other Statutes," 47
Fed. Reg. 20664 (May 13, 1982).
                                -116-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section  III
     l^llt should be noted  that  persons  involved  in  the  administration
of both CERCLA and § 311,  in EPA and  the USCG, have  stated  that  they
prefer the administrative  ease  of § 311.  Objections range  from  the
complexity of the claims and appeals  procedures,  to  the difficulty of
Implementing procurement requirements.  It  is generally recognized
that a program of the size of CERCLA  ($1.6  billion over a five-year
period) merits more careful control than one the  size of $  311  ($100
million over a ten-year period).  However,  it was suggested that a
spill response program requires special flexibility; and Chat  this
need is overshadowed by combining it  with the long-term remedial
program required for abandoned  waste  sites.  It  is possible that such
concerns will be less Important as the  respective EPA and USCG staffs
gain experience in implementing the new law.
                                 -117-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Section  IV
             IV.  EVALUATION'  OF  POTENTIAL  LOSS  CATEGORIES


                                                                Page

A.     Introduction	119

B.     Indemnification  for Disclosure  of Confidential
        Business Information	122

       1.  Description  of the Problem	122
       2.  Evaluation	«	123
       3.  Conclusion	v	124
                          o
C.     Indemnification  for Delays  in EPA Permit Processing  .  .  .   126

       1.  Description  of the Problem	126
       2.  Evaluation	127
       3.  Conclusion	128

D.     Conflicts and Overlaps	130

       1.  Description	130
       2.  Candidate Indemnifiable Situations	130
       3.  Rationale for Indemnfication	131
       4.  Evaluation of Indemnification 	   132

E.     Emergency Powers	134

       1.  Birmingham Air Pollution Alert	134
       2.  Evaluation	135
       3.  Emergency Authority Under Other Statutes	136
       4.  Other Types  of Emergency Resolution Provisions.  .  .  .   137
       5.  Conclusion	138

F.     Unreasonable Enforcement	•	139

       1.  Introduction	139
       2*  The Potential for  Unreasonable Administrative
            Enforcement	139
       3.  Blacklisting	145
       4.  Alternative Remedies and Prevention Mechanisms.  .  •  •   145
       5.  Feasibility and Impacts	146
       6.  Conclusion	147

G.     Changes in Agency Policy	148

       1.  Description of the Problem	148
       2.  Evaluation	148
       3.  Conclusion	•   150

Footnotes	151
                                -118-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
                           A.   INTRODUCTION

       This section of the report concerns the search for potentially
 indemniftable EPA actions in  areas other than merely extensions to
 existing EPA indemnity programs.  In order to determine whether there
 are circumstances which might justify such indemnification, two
 research techniques were used.   First, categories of events were iden-
 tified that  appeared most likely to contain indemnifiable situations.
 Second,  specific  examples of  allegedly indemnifiable situations were
 sought to sharpen the analysis  and assess the seriousness of the
 problems. In each specific case for analysis, indemnification factors
 identified in previous research were applied to determine the poten-
 tial  arguments justifying and opposing the need for indemnification.

       For the first technique,  the easiest general category of events
 to  define were those in which some losses are already indemnified
 under existing EPA programs.   (This category was covered in the pre-
 vious chapter as  "extensions" of existing programs*)  Another category
 involved situations defined to  be similar, but not identical, to
 existing programs.   Still another category concerned situations iden-
 tified by the convergence of  several of  the factors that had been
 determined to be  important in earlier phases of the study.   For
 example,  "emergency action" was chosen because it presents  an
 increased risk of agency error  due to the speed with which  the agency
 decision must be  made,  and because procedural due process may of
 necessity be  suspended.   In addition, the agency may desire to stimu-
 late  speedy action  on the part  of outside parties during emergencies,
 and this  may  warrant use of indemnification as an incentive.

       In  undertaking the search for potentially Indemnifiable situa-
 tions, every  statute and major  regulation implemented by EPA were
 reviewed.  Discussions  were held with past and current EPA  staff to
 learn about the practical operation of the regulations, and particu-
 larly whether there have been or might be indemnifiable losses.  The
 categories identified in the  course of the study guided the search,
 but were  also refined and redefined as additional incidents were iden-
 tified or  reconsidered.

       Industry sources  were also consulted for identification of
 potentially indemnifiable losses.   This  effort included a review of
 surveys  and reports on  regulatory problems in general, including many
 that  had  not  specifically addressed indemnification as a solution to
any regulatory problem.*  In  conjunction with this review,  major
 industry  trade associations were contacted.   Association represen-
 tatives often referred  us to  particular  members who also provided com-
ments  and  information.   As a  result,  a fairly broad perspective of
current  Industry  attitudes toward  EPA regulation and the need for
 indemnification was obtained.2

      Based on the  review of  EPA statutes and regulations and con-
sultation  with Agency and industry spokespersons,  the following cate-
                                 -119-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV



goriee were  selected  for more  detailed  evaluation to determine  the
need  for  Indemnification for potential  losses  due to:

      •   Disclosure  of confidential  business  information;

      •   Delays in Agency action;

      •   Conflicting and overlapping requirements;

      •   Error or overbreadth in Agency  emergency action;

      •   Unreasonable administrative enforcement action; and

      •   Changes in Agency policy.
Each loss area was selected partly because  it was  a  topic  of major
complaint or concern on the part of  industry or  the  agency.  The  loss
categories provide a fairly diverse  representation of  loss types  for
purposes of analysis, but an evaluation of  every industry  complaint or
potential loss would, of course, have been  impossible  within the  scope
of this study.

      Of the three types of indemnification identified and evaluated
in the course of this study (equitable, disincentive,  incentive),
almost all of the categories chosen  for analysis fall  within the
"equitable indemnification'' category.  This Is consistent  with  the
actual historical distribution of indemnification  claims presented to
Congress over the years.

      In considering the following analysis, one must  keep in mind
that government generally does not pay for  the cost  of compliance with
regulatory requirements.  Nor does government normally pay for  the
consequences of the burdens of regulations  unless  those burdens are so
great as to constitute a "taking" of property through  the  almost
complete destruction of its value.  As the  U.S.  Supreme Court recently
restated in Andrus v. Allard, a Fifth Amendment  taking case:

              Suffice it to say that government  regulation
              — by definition — involves.the adjustment  of
              rights for the public good.   Often this
              adjustment curtails some potential for the use
              or economic exploitation of private  property.
              To require compensation in all such  cir-
              cumstances would effectively  compel  the
              government to regulate by purchase.  "Govern-
              ment hardly could go on if to some extent
              values incident to property could  not  be dimi-
              nished without paving for every such change  in
              the general law."*a
                                 -120-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
       There  are very limited exceptions to these general rules.  For
 example,  the federal government provides grant money to assist munici-
 palities  in  complying with the Clean Water Act's wastewater treatment
 requirements.   However,  this involves the federal government assisting
 local  governments,  rather than aiding private regulated parties.  A
 narrow example  of government paying for the indirect burdens of regu-
 lations is the  recently-eliminated beekeepers indemnification program
 in which  payments were made to beekeepers for the consequences of the
 elimination  of  DDT from the marketplace.

       One must  also keep in mind that the federal government already
 has  provided a  broad-based indemnity scheme covering many areas of
 potential loss  to private parties.  Specifically, the Federal Tort
 Claims allows suits for  negligence with certain exceptions, and the
 Tucker Act allows for recovery of contract claims and implements reco-
 very of claims  under the Constitution's Fifth Amendment Taking Clause.

       Thus,  our search for potentially indemnifiable circumstances
 focused on the  narrow,  gray area of exceptional circumstances which
 theoretically fall  outside the existing indemnity schemes provided by
 the  FTCA  and the Tucker  Act,  and yet do not fall into an area of loss
 which  is  considered not  to be compensable.  In other words, for indem-
 nity to be recommended under this study, either the limitations to the
 existing  indemnity  schemes must be removed (e.g., by repealing the
 discretionary function and misrepresentation exceptions to the FTCA),
 or unique circumstances  must be found which Justify an exception to
 those  limits.

       An  example of the  possible wholesale removal of an existing
 limitation would be to permit compensation for governmental "error" in
 the  area  of  policy  formation (rather than for just operational
 negligence).  This  would involve repeal of modification of the discre-
 tionary function exception to the FTCA's waiver of sovereign Immunity.
 This,  of  course,  would pose very serious practical problems of deter-
 mining whether  a discretionary policy judgment among several alter-
 natives can  be  deemed "erroneous."  Unlike the question of operational
 negligence which involves measuring government action against a more
 definite  standard (e.g.,  the terms of the regulation or statute
 itself),  the issue  of policy  error is complicated by the lack of any
 clear-cut way of deciding that the policy judgment was "erroneous" at
 the  time  it  was  made.  Furthermore,  the threat of having to pay com-
 pensation might  seriously impair the policymaker's judgment and have a
 chilling  effect  upon the consideration of various policy alternatives.

       In  sum, there is no support for a recommendation to repeal the
discretionary function exception and authorize a vague, broad standard
of government liability  for "erroneous" policy decisions.
                                 -121-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
                 B.   INDEMNIFICATION FOR DISCLOSURE OF
                     CONFIDENTIAL  BUSINESS  INFORMATION

1.    Description of the  Problem

      Concern  over  possible  industry losses  resulting from disclosure
of confidential  business  information (CB1) submitted  to regulatory
agencies has resulted in  efforts  to get Congress  and  the federal judi-
ciary to define  CBI  more  precisely  and  to  narrow  the  scope of
authorized CBI disclosure or use.

      Although unauthorized  disclosures may  cause some worry, industry
seems to be primarily concerned with authorized disclosures under the
Freedom of Information Act (FOIA) or other statutes.   This is clear
from efforts to  restrict  or  block such  authorized disclosures.   Almost
no industry interest has  been  shown in  providing  indemnification to
private parties  suffering damage  from either authorized or unauthor-
ized government  disclosure of  CBI.

      Much industry  legislative effort  is  now aimed at strengthening
the CBI exemption to the  Freedom of Information Act.3  Amendments to
FIFRA have also  been advanced  that  would alter the disclosure provi-
sions of §§ 3 and 10^ by  providing  for  treble and punitive damages
against a private party who  properly receives CBI for a limited  pur-
pose but then improperly  discloses  the  information.^

      Extensive, but  generally unsuccessful,  industry efforts have
also been undertaken in the  courts  to disallow or restrict intentional
Agency use and disclosure of pesticide  data  under §§  3 and 10 of
FIFRA.6  Some companies have also challenged EPA's authority to  permit
contractors to gain  access to CBI while assisting EPA with inspection
efforts, but only one such judicial challenge has been successful thus
far.^  No complaints  were found concerning EPA contractors wrongfully
disclosing CBI.

      The CBI issue  at EPA has focused  on  pesticides  and toxics
because of Agency acquisition of sensitive product information in
those programs,  and  because  the CBI issue  received extensive congres-
sional scrutiny  while TSCA was being debated•** Elaborate FOIA proce-
dures for authorized EPA release of CBI are  now provided under 40
C.F.R. Part 2, and the Agency has developed  both  TSCA and FIFRA
security manuals designed to safeguard  CBI obtained under those
statutes.^  In addition to EPA's provisions  for employee discipline,
there are criminal sanctions for intentional  unauthorized disclosures.
Title 18 U.S.C.  S 1905 Is a general trade  secrets disclosure prohibi-
tion, and TSCA,  FIFRA, RCRA, and CERCLA also  contain  criminal sanc-
tions against wrongful disclosure.^

      Despite detailed EPA security procedures and apparently very few
disclosure incidents,  there are indications  that  some industry repre-
                                 -122-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
 sentatives  are  still  not comfortable with Agency assurances of ade-
 quate  protection  from unauthorized CBI disclosure.  One industry
 representative  contends  that EPA's disciplinary procedures are not
 sufficiently  severe  to deter unauthorized disclosure by employees.**
 He  also  contends  that potential criminal sanctions for unauthorized
 intentional disclosure do not serve as an effective deterrent.^

       Knowledgeable EPA  and  Justice Department personnel knew of no
 claims filed  against  EPA seeking government compensation due to
 unauthorized  (either  intentional or inadvertent) release of CBI.
 Nor do there  appear  to have  been prosecutions or disciplinary actions
 for intentional and unauthorized disclosure of such information.

       The true  number of improper [disclosures may be difficult to
 ascertain however.  Some disclosures may not be detected,  and an
 affected company  may  be  reluctant to come forward with a complaint for
 fear of  bringing  the  information to the attention of competitors or
 weakening its trade secret status.^  Furthermore, company management
 may fear that its stockholders would be upset that management had
 allowed  the disclosure to occur.

 2.     Evaluation

       Indemnification has not generally been put forward as a remedy
 for the  disclosure of CBI, though one knowledgeable industry represen-
 tative has suggested  use of  such a remedy.     Most industry parties,
 however, seem to  believe that payment of money damages does not deal
 adequately with the problem.   Those concerned with the consequences of
 disclosure of CBI believe that the  solution to such a problem is to
 prevent  disclosure rather than to provide compensation.  Industry thus
 places more emphasis  on  preventing  submission of the information in
 the  first place,  or limiting  the ability of the Agency to  make legally
 authorized disclosures,  than  on ensuring effective EPA security and
 disciplinary provisions  to protect  against  unauthorized or negligent
 disclosures.

       Evaluation  of an indemnification mechanism for CBI disclosure
 requires that distinctions be made  about the various circumstances in
which  CBI can be  disclosed.   First,  there is an important  distinction
between unauthorized  and authorized  disclosures*  Second,  unauthorized
disclosures can be either negligent or Intentional.

      The rationale for  Indemnification can focus on the equitable
need to provide compensation  to the injured party, or on affecting the
behavior of agency employees  so as  to prevent unauthorized disclo-
sures, or on both.  The  former rational is  most important  with respect
 to authorized disclosures.   It may  be possible to permit necessary
disclosure in a way that minimizes  or eliminates the loss  to the party
whose CBI Is released.18  Thus,  the  key question with respect to
authorized disclosures may be whether the burden imposed on the
                                -123-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
 Injured party for the benefit of the public is one for which compensa-
 tion should be paid.  °

       Because indemnification under the § 25(a) study mandate is not
 intended to cover payments that might otherwise be recovered in a tort
 action under the Federal Tort Claims Act, it is necessary to consider
 whether particular types of disclosure losses are already actionable
 under the FTCA.   If disclosure would be judicially actionable, then
 consideration of indemnification is unnecessary.  For the purpose of
 an FTCA analysis, there  are three different categories of disclosure.
 In a case of intentional and unauthorized disclosure, the exception in
 28 U.S.C. § 2860(h) arguably bars an FTCA action, although this pre-
 cise issue has not yet been decided in the courts.^0  Exception (h)
 might similarly  bar an action for negligent disclosure.  Even If it
 does not, the injured party might have difficulty establishing the
 duty of care and proving that it had been breached.^  Finally, cer-
 tain intentional disclosures might be authorized or mandated by
 statute.   For example, TSCA provides authority for release of CBI if
 it is necessary  to protect the public health.22  Because such disclo-
 sures are expressly authorized or required, they would not be action-
 able under the FTCA.   Thus, only this last category of disclosure is
 clearly within the scope of indemnification under this study.

       To  the extent private parties are injured by wrongful government
 disclosure of CBI,  the solution may not be to establish a special EPA
 indemnification  program,  but instead to amend the Federal Tort Claims
 Act  specifically to permit suits for unauthorized disclosures.^  in
 other words,  if  there is a problem,  it is government-wide in scope and
 not  unique to EPA,  and should be dealt with through amendments to the
 FTCA or FOIA.24   Any  attempt to compensate for release of CBI would
 have to solve the administrative problem of how to measure the party's
 loss.   The value of Information,  and expecially the loss of secrecy is
 speculative and  difficult to ascertain.   A compensation program vould
 also have to  overcome the reluctance of a company to advertise the re-
 lease  of  its  information by making a claim.

 3.     Conclusion

       Two of  the criteria discussed  in Section III-A are particularly
 pertinent to  this  evaluation.   CBI releases are clearly addressed more
 effectively by alternatives preventing them than by compensation
afterwards.   Also,  an indemnification program would have very diffi-
cult  administrative problems in defining the value of the release and
 in protecting the  company from further damage in the course of pur-
 suing  Its  claim.   Where  existing  alternatives are not fully satisfac-
tory,  government-wide solutions through amendments to the FOIA or the
FTCA may  be more appropriate to consider than an isolated EPA remedy.

       No EPA  indemnification program seems warranted for losses
resulting  from unauthorized disclosure of CBI.   Evidence of such
                                 -124-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section  IV
unauthorized disclosures appears  to  be  quite  limited,  and  there  are
both criminal sanctions against intentional disclosure and elaborate
security provisions under FIFRA and  TSCA designed  to  safeguard CBI.

      Relevant judicial decisions  involving EPA have  established that
authorized disclosures by the Agency do not amount to  unconstitutional
takings or, in some instances, that  the party  does not have a property
interest in the information.2*  Congressionally-authorized disclosures
designed to protect the public health or welfare are  comparable  to
other regulatory burdens not requiring  compensation.   In many cases,
it may be possible to accomplish  the needed disclosure, while at the
same time protecting the affected  party from loss  or  damage.  Further-
more, much of the conflict over CBI  disclosure involves defining the
term.  Indemnification would not  be  appropriate where  Congress has
already defined certain information  as  not constituting protected CBI
or where Congress had given the Agency  the discretion  to make such a
determination.

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
                    C.   INDEMNIFICATION FOR DELAYS

 1.     Description  of The  Problem

       (a) Delays in Promulgating Regulations

          Although all  types  of  delays in government action were con-
 sidered  in  the  course of  this study,  failure to meet congressionally-
 mandated deadlines for  the promulgation of regulations were determined
 at an  early stage  to be Inappropriate bases for indemnfication.   Cer-
 tainly indemnification  on this basis  would involve severe practical
 problems.   Measuring losses and  determining causation would be diffi-
 cult.  Ascertaining the particular  regulation that would have been
 promulgated, had delay  not occurred,  would amount to pure speculation.
 Costs  may be unacceptable, since great numbers of people are arguably
 adversely affected by the delay  and therefore potentially entitled to
 indemnification.   Such  an indemnity scheme might also be highly
 disruptive  of agency objectives.  Moreover,  a mandatory injunction
 forcing  the agency to discharge  a statutory and non-discretionary duty
 within a particular timetable is available and a preferable alter-
 native relief mechnism  that has  been  used in the past to deal with  ,
 this problem.   For example, in February 1982,  EPA was ordered by the
 U.S. District Court for the District  of Columbia to fulfill its  statu-
 tory duty under the Comprehensive Environmental Response,  Compensa-
 tion,  and Liablity Act of 1980 to promulgate guidelines for emergency
 response actions and to revise and  republish the National  Contingency
 Plan.26  The court  relied on  the statute's mandatory requirement that
 EPA act within  180 days of the statute's enactment.

       (b) Delays in EPA Permit Processing

          Industry representatives  have complained about delays  in
 government  permit  processing,  saying  that these delays have increased
 costs  of financing  or construction  and caused  losses in opportunities
 and profits.^  Industry  sees  the permit-delay problem as  particularly
 accute in the environmental area because of  the complexity of the
 environmental laws  and the Involvement of many different regulatory
 parties.  This complexity, coupled  with slow government action,  has
 allegedly stretched out the total time period  necessary for siting
energy facilities  and other industrial operations.

          Several  studies have indicated that  the causes of delays in
construction of new power plants  and  other facilities are  not limited
 to regulatory problems.   In one  study,  equipment-related and  labor-
related delays appeared to be  much  more important factors  than regula-
tory delays such as changes in requirements  or delays in obtaining
permits.2°  Studies have  also  Indicated that EPA permit processing
appears to  be reasonably  swift,  considering  the complexity of the sta-
 tutory requirements.  For example,  the average permit processing time
 for PSD permits has been  reported to  be less than six months  from the
                                 -126-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
 time of submission of a complete application to the time of issuance.
 (It takes about three months from the initial submission to the time
                                               ?Q
 the application is considered to be complete.)    Despite statistical
 evidence that EPA has a reasonably good permit-processing performance
 record, the Agency has undertaken substantial efforts to assess the
 validity of industry complaints and to evaluate possible improvements
 to make the permit-processing system more efficient.^

           Theoretically,  strict time deadlines could be established,
 and indemnification could be required whenever EPA misses these dead-
 lines.   However,  such an  approach would subject EPA to indemnification
 regardless of its fault and for delays outside the Agency's control.
 On the  other hand, indemnification for losses due to permit-processing
 delays  could be based upon EPA fault.  Such indemnification would be
 premised on the permit applicant's right to timely review of its per-
 mit application and EPA's unreasonable failure to process the applica-
 tion within a certain period of time.

 2.    Evaluation

      Both industry and EPA parties concerned with the problem of per-
 mit delays have focused -on remedial solutions other than Indemnifica-
 tion.   For example, the Business Round table has concentrated on
 identifying potential structural changes to the Clean Air Act which
 would lessen the  complexity and severity of permit requirements.^
 Within  the Agency, efforts have been focused upon tracking the permit
 process and setting average and maximum performance times, reviewing
 possible changes  in substantive and procedural requirements, reviewing
 particular regulations concerning the consolidated permit process, and
 attempting to manage the  existing permit process more effectively.32

      The  Importance of the alternatives to indemnification is height-
 ened because  of the substantial administrative difficulties with
 indemnification.   Unlike  the factual determinations necessary to FIFRA
 §  15, the  determination that a loss was caused by permit delays and
 the measurement of damages would be extremely difficult.  While
 increased  construction costs resulting from delay might be measurable,
 the determination of lost  opportunities and profits would be much more
 problematic.   Of  course,  indemnification could be limited to construc-
 tion cost  or  other readily measurable increases.

      Another administrative problem would  be to determine whether a
delay had  actually been unreasonable.   Although the establishment of a
strict  time  period for permit  processing might provide a simple device
by which to determine  whether  an indemnifiable delay had occurred,
there would be  a  substantial problem in ascertaining the starting
point for  the  time period  to begin to run,  because processing of the
permit  application may have to  await submission of a more complete
application.   Frequently,  applications are  judged so incomplete that
they must  be  returned  to  the applicant for  additional information.  A
                                 -127-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
 similar problem arose in the debates over the proposed Energy
 Mobilization Board when it was supposed to. establish a deadline after
 which a permit would become effective by default.^  This approach was
 concluded  to be impractical because of the difficulty in setting the
 starting date of the permit processing time period.

       Another serious problem is  that the incentives and disincentives
 resulting  from indemnification may have an adverse impact upon the
 environmental objectives of the agency.  An indemnification program
 might substantially shift the focus of agency personnel from the
 quality of permit  review to the speed of that review.  The allowable
 permit processing  time might be Inadequate for complex and controver-
 sial  projects requiring careful evaluation and Involving difficult
 judgments,  and thus might cfoster  the poorest decisions in the hardest
 cases.  Other consequences might  be to prompt EPA employees to waste
 time  developing a  "paper trail" with regard to the completeness of the
 application or in  order to establish evidence that its delay was not
 unreasonable.   EPA might also refrain from getting states to act as
 EPA'a agent in certain situations because of the fear of being subject
 to indemnification for state actions.

       A reverse type of Indemnification is theoretically possible
 where fees  are charged to regulated parties for the costs of permit
 processing.   Under such an approach,  the fee could be waived if EPA
 failed to  process  the permit within a specified time period.  Alter-
 natively,  a higher fee might be charged for "speedy" permit proces-
 sing.   Rather  than using indemnification as a penalty disincentive to
 the agency,  a  fee  approach would  Involve a positive incentive analo-
 gous  to the  bonus  that Amtrak pays  rail lines for "on time" perform-
 ance.   Of  course,  such a scheme could  not be used unless EPA were to
 impose permit-processing fees.^

 3.     Conclusion

       Assuming that  industry is suffering losses due to delays in EPA
 permit processing,  an indemnification  program would not be an appro-
 priate remedial device to  deal  with the problem.  There are five pri-
mary  factors  that  weigh against the use of an indemnification program
 to remedy problems with permit  delays.

       First, the evidence  does  not  show,  in the aggregate, that an
unreasonable amount  of  permit-processing delay is actually occurring.
To the  extent  that  there are  delays in the development of new power
plants  or other industrial  facilities,  regulatory problems (including
permit  processing delays)  are usually  not significant factors in those
delays.  While  there  are some Infrequent situations in which delay
results  solely  from  regulatory  problems,  the difficulties often result
from  the congressionally-determined burden of the requirements and the
complexity of  the  system,  rather  than  from unreasonable agency permit
processing procedures  or from convoluted regulations created by the
agency.
                                 -128-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Section  IV
      Second, regulated parties  usually  do  not  have  (statutory  or
regulatory) rights  to have a  permit  processed within a  particular
time.  If a required time period for processing is exceeded,  then  the
affected party can  bring an action for a mandatory injunction to
remedy the problem.

      Third, to the extent that  permit losses actually  are  resulting
from permit delays, the generally preferred  corrective  solution is to
Improve and speed up the permit  process  instead of paying indemnifica-
tion.  Numerous agency efforts are now underway to accomplish the
objective of Improved permit  processing, even without whatever  stim-
ulus is derived from the fear of indemnification.

      Fourth, there would be  substantial administrative problems
involved in the use of indemnification as a  remedy for  permit delays.
In particular, determination  of  whether  the  delay was unreasonable and
the cause of the loss would be extremely difficult*   Furthermore,  the
determination of the appropriate quantum of  damages  would be  very  dif-
ficult unless standards limiting claimants  to measurable losses in
specified categories were used.

      Fifth, indemnification  would establish counter-productive incen-
tives and disincentives for the  agency and  the  permit applicant.
Indemnification would frequently also conflict  with  agency  objectives.
                                 -129-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
                      D.   CONFLICTS  AND OVERLAPS

 1.     Description

       Conflicting and overlapping regulatory requirements have been a
 principal  target of  regulatory  reformers  and,  to a lesser extent,  may
 serve  as a basis for the  payment of indemnification to those caught in
 the conflict, or forced to  comply with two  sets of regulatory require-
 ments.  In fact, however, regulatory conflict  and overlap do not
 appear to  be an important problem at EPA, relative to other regulatory
 issues.  This is partly because all of the  major environmental statu-
 tes include provisions directing that EPA coordinate its activities,
 both between separate divisions and with  other agencies of the federal
 and state  governments.

       Regulatory conflict occurs when compliance with one regulatory
 requirements results in the inability to  comply with another require-
 ment.   Regulatory overlap occurs when separate regulations with simi-
 lar objectives are aimed at a single activity  or process.

 2.     Candidate Indemnifiable Situations

       (a)  Interacting Requirements

           Interacting requirements  are those where compliance with one
 requirement brings a party  within the scope of regulations in another
 area.   If  the second regulation conflicts with the first, such that it
 is impossible to comply with both,  then the interacting requirements
 have caused a loss which is Impossible to avoid,  and thus a candidate
 for indemnification.   The Trie  situation  is alleged by some to fit
 this model  of Interacting requirements.37

          A recent GAO study identified 20  instances of interacting
 requirements involving federal  agencies,  including four that involve
EPA.3®  An example involving EPA is presented  by the fact that as  many
as 26 of the wastes  listed  as hazardous under  EPA's hazardous waste
 regulations are generated bv the proper operation of water and air
 pollution  control devices.    These'devices capture toxic pollutants
 in the  form of sludge which must be disposed of in accordance with
EPA's RCRA regulations.  This example is  typical of interacting
requirements in that  compliance with air  or water regulations creates
 the need to comply with RCRA standards.   It differs from the Tris
example, however, because RCRA does not prohibit the generation of
 toxic sludge, but merely subjects it  to' additional regulatory
standards.

       (b) Overlapping Jurisdiction

          Overlapping jurisdiction  occurs when two or more agencies or
offices have requirements regarding the same product,  substance or
                                -130-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
 process.   The  GAO identified  14  examples of overlapping jurisdiction
 problems,  including  six  involving EPA.  ^

           An  illustrative  example is presented by the fact that sac-
 charin  is  listed  as  a  hazardous  waste under RCRA, because of its car-
 cinogenic  properties,  while the  FDA continues to approve it as a food
 additive.  When  two  or more agencies or offices have jurisdiction over
 a  single product  or  activity,  the potential for inconsistent treatment
 such  as this  is  increased.  Overlapping jurisdiction therefore, may be
 thought of as  forcing  regulated  parties to incur the added costs of
 complying  with two sets  of regulations, when it would arguably be more
 efficient  for  there  to be  a single "integrated" set of requirements.

      (c)  Duplicate  Enforcement

           Duplicate  enforcement  occurs  when two or more agencies have
 responsibility for investigating complaints, issuing permits,  or con-
 ducting inspections  for  similar  or related purposes.  The GAO  found 18
 examples of duplicate  enforcement in its report, including 10
 involving  EPA.*1

           For example, both EPA  and the states make inspections under
 both  the Clean Air Act and the Clean Water Act.  These inspections
 occur at different times and  require that Information be presented in
 different  formats.   A  similar problem may be presented if a single
 enterprise must apply  for and obtain two or more permits for separate
 agencies or offices.   To the  extent that these permits serve similar
 purposes,  or enforcement actions are aimed at similar conduct, they
 force regulated parties  to incur expenses not otherwise imposed.

 3.    Rationale for  Indemnflcatlon

      The  rationale  for  indemnification is slightly different  for
 interacting requirements than for the other types of conflicts and
overlaps.  Where  interacting requirements are the asserted basis for
 indemnification,  the rationale is that  compliance with one requirement
 forces the regulated party to comply with another requirement.  Thus
 the regulated party  has  incurred a double expense,  made necessary only
because of the manner  in which the first regulation operates.   If the
second regulation amounts to a total prohibition, then the affected
party is caught in an  impossible situation:   compelled by one  regula-
tion to do what is prohibited by a second regulation.

      With respect to  overlapping jurisdications and duplicate
enforcement,  the  rationale for indemnification is that regulatory
activity designed to deal with the particular regulated party  affected
could be designed to achieve the same effect at lower cost to  that
party if only a single agency or office were responsible for the
party's activity or  product.  Since it  is the structure of EPA, rather
than the nature of the regulated activity,  that imposes the double
compliance costs, these costs should be indemnified.
                                 -131-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
 4.     Evaluation of Indemnification

       The GAO has concluded that the problems of regulatory conflict
 and overlap are not as serious as regulatory reform advocates
 assert.^  Moreover,  where they exist, they do not necessarily produce
 a loss,  as that term is ordinarily defined.  While compliance costs
 may be greater where regulatory conflicts and overlaps exist, when
 compared to the situation where a single office is responsible for
 controlling all aspects of a party's activities, these increased costs
 are not  losses, in the traditional sense, because there is no reason
 to  suppose that regulated parties are entitled to regulatory programs
 designed to minimize  compliance costs.  Indeed, EPA is certainly
 entitled to structure its regulatory'efforts so as to minimize its own
 administrative costs  or 
-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Section IV
interference with EPA objectives, are more readily administered by the
Agency, and do not involve the potential for enormous expenditures.
For these reasons, and indemnifty program can not be recommended in
preference to the available alternatives.
                                 -133-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
                         E.   EMERGENCY POWERS

    Any  action  taken  quickly in an emergency is more likely to have
some untoward consequences  than actions taken with enough time to
investigate, deliberate and consult.   If,  in addition,  agency action
requires an immediate response  from regulated parties,  the possibility
of loss  is increased.   The  parties cannot  avoid or reduce the loss by
objecting before  implemention of the  agency order.  A well known
example  of emergency  agency action,  requiring immediate response,
Illustrates the theoretical problems.

1.  Birmingham Air Pollution Alert43

    Birmingham has had a long history of air pollution  problems
because  It is a mining and  metallurgical center located between moun-
tains which often prevent the dispersion of air pollution created by
industry.  At the time of the air pollution emergency in November,
1971, the state had just enacted,  but had  not yet  implemented,  an air
pollution control law.   The state was also drafting Its State
Implementation Plan,  including  Its plans for handling air pollution
emergencies.  Thus, there was neither a federal nor a state regulatory
structure, and no authority delegated to local officals to respond to
the episode.

    The  local health  department tried to obtain voluntary reduction of
the particulate emissions causing the emergency.   Some  of the indus-
trial sources responded,  but  those contributing most to the problem
did not.^*  As it became evident that the  efforts  of the county health
department were failing,  and  the Weather Service predicted a con-
tinuing  inversion, EPA officals decided to use the emergency authority
in § 303 of the Clean  Air Act to force emission reductions.  The pro-
vision had been in the  Act  since 1967,  but had never been used.
Nevertheless, EPA and  Justice attorneys and local  health officials put
together the necessary  papers in six  or seven hours.

    For  reasons that  are not  entirely clear ten years later, none of
the 23 industrial sources named in the Temporary Restraining Order
(TRO) were informed that  it was being sought.   The judge granted the
TRO at 1:45 a.m.  on November  18 after an ex parte  hearing.  Soon after,
the sources were  telephoned to  inform them of the  order.  Most  were
asked to postpone or  reduce operations to  the extent possible without
damage to equipment, rather than to shut down completely.  For
example, the U.S. Steel  Falrfield Works was required to Increase
coking time to the maximum  extent  possible,  and to reduce emissions
from open hearth  furnaces by  ceasing  feed,  but was allowed to maintain
heat in  the furnaces.^   The  TRO was  in effect for 32 hours.  By the
time of  the hearing set  for the preliminary injunction, the weather
had changed, bringing  rain.

    The attorneys.for  the affected facilities expressed indignation at
the lack of notice and  the  midnight hearing.   Some also complained
                                 -134-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
 that their clients should not have been included in the order because
 they had  installed pollution control equipment or were too far away to
 be  contributing to the  emergency.   One attorney who represented eight
 or  nine of the sources  said that,  if the order had lasted longer and
 greater losses had been incurred,  they certainly would have sought
 indemnification for their losses.  "

 2.   Evaluation

     If  it  is  true, as alleged,  that some of the named facilities were
 not  contributing to the air pollution emergency and thus were errone-
 ously included in the order,  an argument can be made for indemnifica-
 tion.   Errors made in such a situation are more serious than at other
 times because they lead to irreversible harm.   The affected parties
 had  no  opportunity to pursuade  the Agency or the Judge that they
 should  be  removed from  the list.   There was no notice, and no oppor-
 tunity  to  prepare for the new regulation.   (On the other hand, it was
 clear to all  that the situation was serious.  Apparently, visibility
 was so poor  in places  that driving was nearly impossible.)  The
 order,  though denominated a "temporary restraining order" had irre-
 versible impact.   There was no  way to appeal or to have the TRO
 reviewed before it took effect.

     For those properly  addressed,  indemnification would not be
 justified.  Their costs were  only  those of complying with a proper
 Agency  action taken to  protect  the public  from an imminent health
 hazard.  This was precisely the  situation  in which Congress had
 intended §  303 to be used.*7

     In  this case,  though there  appears to  have been some procedural
unfairness  and possible error,  the loss was limited by the short
 period, and the way in  which  the order was written.  It should be
 remembered  that drastic action  was taken only  after requests for
voluntary action  had failed,  and the  situation threatened the health
of a large  population.   Similar  losses are possible in the future, but
unlikely.  The primary  response  to future  emergencies will be made by
the 'state under their SIP's.  This will cure many of the problems of
the  emergency response  in Birmingham.^ The industry has had a good
deal of notice of  what  will be expected as each level of pollution is
reached.  The triggers  for  successive stages of control are designated
ahead of time*  The regulations are developed  with opportunity for
comment and with  the substantive assistance of the affected parties.
Therefore, error  will be  less likely  because of the consultation, and
cooperation more  likely since the  sources  helped write the plans.

    Application of  the  criteria for decisions  discussed in Section
III-A,  to a situation like  Birmingham provides guidance for future
Incidents, though it Is not clearly for or against payment of
indemnification.
                                 -135-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
     Providing indemnification for an individual incident would most
 likely  have the objective of correcting an inequity.  Thus, the first
 determination would be whether the agency action was indeed inequit-
 able.   This requires a collection of all the facts. In the Birmingham
 situation a decision-maker balanced the refusal of some of the sources
 to  cooperate and the clear danger to the public health against the
 government's precipitous and perhaps overbroad action.  No formula or
 criteria can substitute for an analysis of the particular facts.

     Alternatives to Indemnification are fewer during emergencies than
 at  other times.   For example, exceptions or waivers to agency orders
 might  undermine  the purpose of the action, and take too long to pro-
 pose and approve.   There are however, many ways to limit losses that
 might  be incurred  during an emergency, and the environmental statutes
 contain many examples.  TSCA requires hearings before or within five
 days of emergency  actions thus limiting the time an unchallenged
 emergency order  could be In effect*

     The language of the emergency powers sections make it clear that
 Congress has accepted greater compliance costs in an emergency than
 for  ordinary regulations.  Such expressions of congressional opinion
 should be taken  into account in deciding what losses warrant
 Indemnification.

     The possibility that the payments of an indemnity might have a
 chilling effect  on future agency action is more serious in relation to
 emergencies  because the threat to public health is by definition
 imminent and substantial.

 3.   Emergency Authority Under Other Statutes

     Virtually all  pollution control statutes Implemented by EPA have
 provisions  similar to § 303 of the CAA.  These provisions respond to
 the  common  need  to act quickly to alleviate immediate threats to
 health or the environment that could not have been prevented by ordi-
 nary regulatory  mechanisms.  These extraordinary measures are most
 needed before the  rest of the regulatory structure is in place, as
 demonstrated in  the Birmingham incident, but there will continue to be
 accidents or occurrences not controlled by regulation.

     Like the Air Act,  the Clean Water Act now regulates most emissions
 of pollutants.   Emergencies,  however, are probably most likely with
 respect  to unregulated emissions, although they can occur as the
 result  of breakdowns of otherwise functioning processes, or other unu-
 sual situations.   Under the Clean Water Act as well, internal and
 external review  is required before taking action,  even in emergency
 situations.   Both  Agency officials and the Department of Justice must
 approve  requests  to seek court orders-.  The judge acts as independent
 decision maker,  balancing the threat to the public against the cost.
The  power to shut  down an operation has only been used once under the
                                  -136-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
 CWA, to temporarily halt operation of an FMC plant in West Virginia
 that was leaking large amounts of carbon tetrachloride into the Kanawa
 River.   (It took three days to clear the request to apply for a TRO
 even though the drinking water of large populations downstream was
 seriously threatened.)

     The Comprehensive Environmental Response, Compensation and
 Liability Act (Superfund) provides a coordinated response to emergen-
 cies caused by release of hazardous substances into the air, water, or
 land.   It authorizes direct action by the government in cleaning up or
 containing a spill,  as well as providing authority to issue a
 presidential order or seek injunctive relief.  Private parties
 assisting in the cleanup may be reimbursed for their efforts under
 certain conditions.   Many of the features of the new law should help
 to  reduce unreasonable losses that might be Imposed on private parties
 during  environmental emergencies.  Action based on the National
 Contingency Plan,  like action under a regulation, will not surprise
 those whom it affects.  It should also be less likely to be erroneous
 or  unfair since the  NCP was developed over a decade with wide partici-
 pation.   The ability of the agency to take direct action should also
 reduce  burdens on  private parties.  Even in cases in which the govern-
 ment later sues responsible parties for reimbursement, the more
 leisurely determination of responsibility should prevent errors and
 overbroad orders.

     The  ability of  the agency to take direct action creates a new
 source  of liability:   the losses that may be incurred by firms hired
 to  clean up hazardous waste sites or spills.  Handling hazardous waste
 is  a dangerous and unfamiliar process,  and potential contractors have
 refused  to  undertake  cleanups without some indemnification from the
 government  for their  potentially large  liability to third parties.
 Because  commercial insurance is not available in the quantities neces-
 sary to  cover  potential losses, EPA has indicated that It will try to
 indemnify contractors for losses above  the required one million
 dollars  of  commercial liability insurance.  ®D  The  indemnification
 clauses  in  the contracts  are conditioned on the availability of funds.

 4.   Other Types  of Emergency Resolution Provisions

     Although Congress has provided a catch-all emergency mechanism in
each environmental statute  to address Imminent and  substantial harms,
 there are also usually other,  more specific emergency response provi-
 sions in  each  statute.  Often the agency can prevent or respond to an
emergency without Invoking  emergency authority, for example through
 its  enforcement  powers.   In many cases  a pollution  emergency will
result from a  release that  violates a specific statutory prohibition
 (e.g., §  301 of  the CWA)  or the terms of a permit*   Therefore adequate
abatement authority will  exist under the enforcement provision of the
statute.  In such cases the underlying  standards  are usually clear,
and  industry will have participated in  the  development of the regula-
                                -137-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
tions or in permit negotiations*   Enforcement actions are  subject  to
internal review and provide  opportunity to contest the action  in
court.  Thus, there should be  less of  a chance of  error or unreason-
able action by the agency*

5.  Conclusion

    There does not seem to be  a justification for  further  Indemnifica-
tion programs related to emergencies at this  time. EPA has rarely
used its emergency authority in the past,  and there is no  reason to
believe that use of the conventional authorities will increase*  A new
and comprehensive law governs  response to  emergencies generated  by
release of hazardous substances*   It appears  to limit the  posslblities
for unwarranted burdens on private parties.   Until more experience
indicates a need for assistance beyond Superfund and  the provisions
for clean up contractors, no new  Indemnification program should  be
recommended.
                                 -138-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
                      F.   UNREASONABLE ENFORCEMENT

 1.   Introduction

     Under  §  113(b)  of the Clean Mr Act,  and  other similar statutes,  a
 person  subject  to unreasonable  enforcement  may recover attorneys fees
 and  other  reasonable  costs of  litigation.   He may also recover similar
 costs associated with formal agency adjudicative actions under the
 Equal Access  to Justice  Act (although the  standards of recovery are
 different).   The purposes in such  provisions  are to encourage a person
 to present a  legitimate  defense who would  otherwise not do so because
 of the  expense  involved,  and to dissuade  the  agency from taking
 unreasonable  action.  '

     These  provisions,  however,  stop short  of  remedying and discour-
 aging unreasonable  administrative  action  that will never proceed to
 trial — perhaps precisely because the agency has determined  that its
 initial action  was  unreasonable.   It is acknowledged at EPA that there
 is potential  for error and harrassment in  administrative enforcement,
 although they are thought to be infrequent  and very rarely inten-
 tional.  Given  the  clear  expression of congressional policy to remedy
 and  prevent unreasonable  judicial  enforcement by the use of an
 attorneys' fees indemnity provision,  a logical inquiry is whether
 there should  be a similar policy to remedy  and prevent unreasonable
 administrative  enforcement (especially since  experience indicates that
 unreasonable  judicial  enforcement  will rarely occur).

     The following discussion explores the  potential for unreasonable
 administrative  enforcement in EPA  programs, explores the potential for
 alternative remedies  to  Indemnification, and  considers the feasibility
 and  impacts of  such an indemnification program.

 2.   The Potential for  Unreasonable Administrative Enforcement

     The potential for  "unreasonable"  enforcement is inherent  in any
 administrative  program that relies on enforcement to ensure implemen-
 tation of standards.   Almost all of the major statutory programs under
 EPA  jurisdiction contain  substantial  enforcement authority, and
 Congress has  traditionally authorized significant staff levels and
 funds for enforcement  purposes.  In addition,  many of  the statutes
 contain enforcement imperatives, and  Congress has frequently  reviewed
EPA*s enforcement record  with an eye  toward promoting  more action.

    The Term  "Unreasonable"

    What constitutes "unreasonable"  enforcement  is necessarily a
matter of interpretation.  Many would probably agree if enforcement
 amounts to intentional harrassment or if the  agency has committed an
 error in determining the  existence of a violation or the applicability
 of a regulation, or proceeded to enforce without a good faith legal
 justification,  that these  actions  would be  "unreasonable."
                                 -139-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
     Undoubtedly,  however,  there are other circumstances which persons
 would argue  amount  to  unreasonable actions, but over which there would
 be legitimate  disagreement.   Typical past complaints against EPA
 enforcement  policies  include:   (1) enforcement of technically or eco-
 nomically  infeasible  requirements (where the Agency intends to Imple-
 ment statutory mandates);  (2)  Inconsistent enforcement practices, for
 example, in  the assessment of  penalties (where the Agency utilizes its
 inherent discretion to enforce as it sees fit under the circum-
 stances);  (3)  discriminatory selection of enforcement cases —for
 example, the Agency may publicize an enforcement target list, as under
 RCRA and CERCLA,  that  includes certain violators who may pose a less
 significant  environmental  risk than others who are excluded from the
 list (in such  a case  the Agency's enforcement interest may be based on
 other factors, such as location,  adequacy of evidence, visibility for
 purposes of  deterrence,  etc.);  and (4) the use of harsh bargaining
 techniques (for example, the Agency may threaten to pursue all
 available  or particularly  burdensome sanctions as leverage to obtain
 acceptance of  certain  unfavorable terms in a consent decree).

     For purposes  of the current evaluation, the latter circumstances
 are  excluded from further  consideration,  and a narrow view of
 "unreasonable" enforcement has been chosen.  Such a view is consistent
 with congressional  consideration of the issue under § H3(b) of the
 Clean Air Act  and the  Equal  Access to Justice Act.50  Moreover, the
 latter circumstances are almost always within the broad province of
 enforcement discretion typically provided by Congress and accorded by
 the  courts.^

     The Term "Enforcement"
    Typically, an enforcement  program  embraces  all aspects  of  regula-
tion design and implementation,  from assistance in regulation  drafting
(or review) to ensure enforceability,  to  the initiation and completion
of appropriate administrative  and  judicial  proceedings.  The list  of
enforcement responsibilities in  any one of  EPA's enforcement programs
is quite long, Including such  activities  as preparing  guidelines and
manuals; conducting workshops; reviewing  state  regulations  and
enforcement actions; reviewing permit  applications and compliance
reports; conducting inspections  and other* compliance  Investigations;
responding to private complaints and inquiries; preparing and  issuing
informal compliance evaluations, formal notices, and abatement orders;
conducting formal and informal meetings and hearings for purposes  of
due process, negotiation; assessing and collecting penalties;  pre-
paring and negotiating consent decrees; assisting in litigation; and
numerous other activities. *

    Of principal concern here  are  administrative enforcement pro-
ceedings that impose or could  lead to  the imposition of specific
sanctions.  Inspections and other  preenforcement investigations are
excluded,53 aa well as informal  negotiations, and the  numerous formal
                                 -140-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Section  IV
activities  that involve rulemaking,  permitting,  and  similar  activities
(e.g., delegations of enforcement authority, approval and  issuance  of
delayed compliance orders and nonferrous  smelter orders under  the
Clean Air Act, response to State submissions and the issuance  of NPDES
permits under the Clean Water Act, etc.)*  Emergency actions have also
been excluded because they are discussed  separately  in this  chapter.

    In general, four types of administrative enforcement activities
have been given consideration:  (1)  notices of violation,  (2)  compli-
ance orders, (3) administrative penalties, and (4) the use of
blacklisting.  The following table indicates which statutes  contain
these four  administrative enforcement techniques.
                Administrative Enforcement Mechanism
Statute
CAA
CWA
RCRA
SDWA
FIFRA
TSCA
CERCLA
NOV
Authority^*
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Compliance
Orders
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
_—
Yes
Penalties
Yes
Yes
—
	
Yes
Yes
	
                                                        Blacklisting

                                                            Yes
                                                            Yes
    a.  Existing Constraints to Unreasonable Administrative Enforce-
        ment

        There are numerous factors that protect persons from unreason-
able administrative enforcement action by EPA.  These Include statu-
tory enforcement restrictions; Agency concurrence and review
procedures; Agency policies favoring state enforcement leadership,
informal disputes resolution, and concentration on only the most
"significant" violators; as well as overall resource constraints.   It
should be noted that these factors, either alone or In combination,
offer no assurance that unreasonable enforcement will not occur; and
they vary in significance from program to program.  Nonetheless, they
offer a general perspective on the potential for unreasonable enforce-
ment at EPA and help to explain why there are few complaints relating
to EPA enforcement that are being raised by industry.

        (1)  Statutes

             EPA's statutes include two types of constraints on
enforcement that would limit the occurrence of unreasonable action:
(1) provisions that limit EPA's enforcement authority; and (2) proce-
dural requirements that enable persons subject to enforcement to
influence the Agency's action.
                                -141-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATON STUDY
                                             Section IV
              There are numerous statutory constraints on administra-
 tive enforcement authority.  Under § 113(a) of the Clean Air Act, for
 example, EPA has interpreted the statute to require that administra-
 tive orders provide for compliance within thirty days.  If this is not
 feasible, the Agency must pursue judicial action under § 113(b).
 Thus, the flexibility to take formal administrative enforcement action
 under the Clean Air Act is often restricted.  Another type of restric-
 tion exists under §§ 1414 and 1423 of the Safe Drinking Water Act:
 EPA findings of noncompliance must be turned over to  any state which
 has been given primary enforcement responsibility by EPA; then, unless
 EPA finds that the State has abused its enforcement discretion, EPA's
 role is  limited to advice and assistance.55  These, and similar con-
 straints which exist under other statutes limit the potential for
 unreasonable action by limiting the occurrence of administrative
 enforcement altogether.

              On the other hand, procedural prerequesites to enforce-
 ment often permit or induce an independent check on the validity of an
 action and allow for errors to be  identified and resolved prior to the
 occurrence of any significant adverse impact.   For example, many of
 the statutes impose notice of violation and conference or hearing
 requirements prior to the issuance of an order or assessment of a
 penalty;56 and special statutory hearings and  appeals procedures exist
 for certain enforcement  actions."  Where statutes do not provide for
 these procedures,  agency policies  often do.58

         (2)   Policies

              Other areas which might raise the potential for unreason-
 able enforcement  have been deemphasized or eliminated by current
 agency policies.   For example,  under the pesticides law EPA has
 adopted  a  policy  emphasizing compliance assistance to industry as well
 as  state agencies  and deemphaslzing independent enforcement.59  Shifts
 of  emphasis  may also  be  noted under other programs, particularly under
 the  Clean  Air Act,  the Clean Water Act,  and  the Safe Drinking Water
 Act.60

              This  is  considered appropriate  not only as a matter of
 fiscal constraint  and efficient resource allocation,  but also as an
 important  element  of  the current administration's policy of "coopera-
 tive" or "new" federalism.   As  an  example of how this policy would be
 Implemented  in one  program,  a recent  air pollution enforcement policy
memorandum instructs  the Regional  Offices to encourage states to take
 the  lead in  enforcement  against "significant violators," to offer
assistance,  and to  assume  the lead  only  where  a State cannot  or will
not  take the  lead,  despite whatever assistance EPA can provide.^

              It is  also  apparent that  the agency intends to concen-
 trate its enforcement  against predetermined  "significant"  violators.
Each program  office has  developed  criteria  for identifying such
                                 -142-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATON STUDY
                                             Section IV
 violators, and in some cases, lists have already been or are being
 prepared.   In general, this policy is an element of the Administra-
 tor's new  accountability system, intended to remove enforcement quotas
 as  a measure of performance and to instate criteria based on environ-
 mental results.62  Guidance under the stationary source air program,
 for example, provides that "significant violators" are existing faci-
 lities located in or affecting non attainment areas with controlled
 emissions  exceeding a 250 tons per year potential, unless the magni-
 tude and duration of the violation is minimal and non-recurring; new
 and hazardous facilities are normally considered significant (again,
 unless the violation is minimal and non recurring)."  Identification
 of  facilities meeting these criteria and development of specific
 enforcement strategies are to involve state participation.64

              A coordinated approach toward identification of enforce-
 ment targets In advance limits the potential for error associated with
 hasty or negligent action.  In addition, Administrator Gorsuch has
 stated that a "non-confrontational" approach to enforcement is pre-
 ferred —  one that presumes good faith by the regulated industry and
 emphasizes voluntary compliance.65  Such an approach may be Indicated
 by  the reduction in cases forwarded to the Department of Justice for
 litigation since Gorsuch took offlee,66 as well as in recent EPA
 efforts to involve industry in self-regulation programs.67

        (3)  Concurrence Procedures

              To ensure that these national policies are observed, as
 well as to ensure legal adequacy, internal enforcement concurrence
 procedures are stressed.   These procedures are especially rigorous
 when litigation is involved.68  However, to preserve the option of
 litigation,  the litigation concurrence procedures also serve as an
 incentive  toward careful  case consideration at the outset.69  For
 administrative action they currently require that the Regional Counsel
 approve the action as legally adequate and consistent with national
 policy.^O   Normally,  the  action must also be signed by an official
 high enough within the managing hierarchy (e.g.,  Division Director) so
 that  several  levels  of review will have occurred  before the action is
 forwarded  to  counsel  for  concurrence.

        (4)   Overall  Resource Constraints

              It  is possible that the potential for unreasonable admin-
 istrative  enforcement may also be influenced by enforcement resource
 limitations.   Fewer  resources,  for example,  may result in more careful
 case  selection.   Traditionally,  EPA enforcement  resources have per-
mitted  only  a limited number of enforcement  cases,  and these have been
 chosen  on  a  selective basis.   Recently,  moreover,  as a part of the
 overall administration initiative to conserve federal resources and
 achieve a  balanced budget,  EPA's enforcement resources have been cur-
 tailed  even  further.
                                 -143-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
             During F.Y.  1982,  EPA's  overall  operating  budget  for
enforcement was  reduced by  12%  (reflecting  efficiencies attained by
management and reorganization according  to  testimony by Gorsuch before
the Senate Public Works Committee  in  1981).71  EPA's budget  request
for 1983, moreover, Indicates that  In certain program areas, more
reductions may occur.^   However,  the Administration has indicated
that these proposed reductions  for  the most part  will not result in  an
actual decrease  in enforcement  activity  from  1982 levels. Further,  a
portion of the individual program decreases have  merely been shifted
to a new Office  of Enforcement  Counsel,  (within the  recently estab-
lished Office of Legal and  Enforcement Counsel) as a part of an
overall reorganization of enforcement operations. Thus, whether
currently planned reductions in enforcement resources will result in
more selective enforcement  would be a matter  of speculation.

    b.  Absence  of Complaints

        During the course of this study,  substantial research  was con-
ducted to determine the existence of  actual complaints  involving
unreasonable EPA enforcement.   Enforcement  officials currently with
the Agency (or who recently departed) were  interviewed.  Major
industry associations were  consulted, and relevant reports and con-
gressional documents were reviewed.7* Although this research  was
neither comprehensive nor designed  scientifically to ensure  statisti-
cal validity, very few Instances were identified  in  which complaints
pertained to unreasonable enforcement, as defined in the current
analysis.  In fact, only  in recent  Senate Oversight  Hearings involving
the Clean Air Act were complaints alleging  specific  losses due to EPA
enforcement actions raised.7*   Even in these  situations, however,
objections related to EPA's use of  its legal  discretion, not to
errors, negligence or action amounting to an  abuse of process.

        It is not possible  to conclude from this  research that no EPA
enforcement action to date  warrants indemnification.  To the extent
that such actions may exist, however, they  have not  been openly pub-
licized.  Several respondents during  the  course of this study  sug-
gested that the  absence of  Industry complaints  may reflect concern
over bad publicity and fear of  compounding  existing  agency relation-
ship problems by raising  the issue.

        On the other hand,  testimony  does appear  throughout  the past
several years criticizing EPA's failure  to  conduct adequate  enforce-
ment.  This is particularly noticeable in the 1981 enforcement over-
sight hearings,  as well as  in recent  oversight  hearings on the
implementation of the Clean Water Act, the  Resource  Conservation and
Recovery Act, and Superfund;75  and  in legislative hearings on  the
budget and the Clean Air  Act reauthorization.7^
                                 -144-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATON STUDY
                                             Section IV
 3.   Blacklisting

         An area of concern frequently raised in interviews involved
 the  agency's blacklisting authority.  Under the Clean Air and Clean
 Water Acts,'  no federal agency may engage in a contract with a person
 who  is convicted of a criminal violation (unless the President provi-
 des  a special  exemption) until EPA certifies that the condition giving
 rise to the conviction no longer exists.  Expanding upon this author-
 ity, Executive Order 11738,  § 4,78 requires that all federal procure-
 ments include  provisions requiring compliance with the Clean Air and
 Water Acts.  Accordingly, EPA has established blacklisting criteria
 under 40 C.F.R.  § 15.20(a)(l) that include not only criminal convic-
 tions,  but  other instances of non-compliance.

         Blacklisting,  of course, is intended to interfere with a
 company's  ability to obtain new procurements and thus may have a cal-
 culable economic impact that would vary depending, among numerous
 factors, on the  amount of federal procurements anticipated by a given
 company, the timing of these procurements, the Investment already
 incurred,  and  the time period necessary to obtain delisting.  The
 stigma  attached  may also be  more serious than that associated with
 other administrative enforcement actions,  since, in contrast to most
 administrative and judicial  enforcement cases, the list Is published
 in the  Federal Register,   and the Administrator's listing determina-
 tion would  therefore be more widely publicized.

         In  general,  however,  this procedure has not often been
 utilized.  In part this is because by the time a criminal conviction
 occurs,  the  underlying violation has been  corrected;  and most civil
 actions  are  resolved by settlement or consent decree.  In addition,
 the  agency  rarely considers  listing except in the context of exascer-
 bated cases  or repeated offenses,  and the  opportunity for error is
 substantially  limited  in those cases.  Moreover, listing does not
 occur automatically  because  a facility is  in violation.   Rather,  it
must  be  the  result of  a specific recommendation (by certain EPA
 officials, governors or the  public),  followed by an independent EPA
 case  examination,  which includes an opportunity for the owner of  the
 facility to  present  evidence,  and it is ultimately effected by a
 "listing review  panel."80

4.  Alternative Remedies and  Prevention Mechanisms

    If unreasonable  enforcement  actually occurs, and  relief within the
agency is not  available,  a lawsuit to prevent further such action
would be the most  logical alternative.   However, if losses have been
 incurred because  of  the initial  agency action,  they probably.cannot be
 recovered.   Further, unless  the  party qualifies as a  small business
under the Equal Access to Justice Act,  it  may not be  able to recover
court costs  for  his  successful lawsuit.  Compensation for other
 losses,  such as  lost business,  is  not available in any case.   In  addi-
                                 -145-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATON STUDY
                                             Section IV
 tion,  If  the agency  is  not  obligated  to  pay  compensation,  then  one  of
 the  primary purposes  in current  legislation  may  not  be  fulfilled  — to
 deter  unreasonable action by  forcing  the  agency  to pay  —  although  the
 lawsuit,  itself, may  be an  adequate deterrent  In this regard.

        Nonetheless,  It is  possible that  injury  may  be  avoided  alto-
 gether through judicial review.  However, courts have often been
 unwilling to allow suits at an early  stage of  the enforcement process,
 on the theory that review should be limited  to final agency action, as
 defined under the Administrative Procedure Act or the specific  statu-
 tes  involved.81  However, not all courts  agree that  review must await
 some later stage of enforcement, if a demonstration  of  immediate, harm-
 ful  impact can be made: and the  trend appears  to be  more toward flexi-
 bility on this issue.82 Judicial review  will  usually be permitted  if
 it can be demonstrated  that administrative remedies  are inadequate,
 futile, will result in  irreparable injury, or  would  be  void.8''

 5.  Feasibility and Impacts

    If there is a right to  such compensation for unreasonable adminis-
 trative enforcement,  or even  if  the indemnity  is subject to court
 discretion, an indemnification program could invite  lawsuits at any
 stage  of administrative procedures prior  to  their completion, and thus
 supplant administrative enforcement discretion entirely — or,  at a
 minimum, require a judicial proceeding on the  issue  of  indemnification
 prior  to completion of  the  agency proceeding.  This  illogical result,
 along  with the high potential for chilling administrative  enforcement
 activity would argue  for making an award  only  at the completion of  the
 agency proceeding.  A more  appropriate course  would  be  to  ensure  the
 availability of enforcement review whenever  agency action, regardless
 of the stage, poses a significant threat  of  immediate Injury, and a
 facial demonstration  is made  that the agency action  is  erroneous  or
 amounts to an abuse of  process.

    A  second important  consideration  relates to  the  amount of compen-
 sation.  Fees associated with enforcement defense are readily calcul-
 able if they involve  retaining outside experts or if the defendant  has
 hired  such experts for  the  purpose of defending  the  case.   However, if
 inside staff are used,  it may be difficult to  show that an unantici-
 pated  expense has occurred  as the result  of  unreasonable enforcement.
Lost profits and other  opportunity costs  may prove to be too specula-
 tive.  Again, the most  logical approach would  be to  ensure that a
 cause  of action exists  in clearly warranted  cases so that  judicial
 review may be obtained  prior  to incurring business losses.

    Finally, one should balance the need  for compensation  and the
 interest in deterring unreasonable enforcement against  the strong con-
 gressional policy toward enforcement  under most  EPA  statutes.
Especially in the absence of any evidence that unreasonable enforce-
ment occurs on more than isolated occasions, and in  the presence  of
                                 -1A6-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATON STUDY
                                             Section IV
evidence  that all enforcement will  be  subject  to  close  scrutiny,  it
may  not be  reasonable  to establish  unnecessary legislative  constraints
to EPA enforcement.

6.   Conclusion

     An expanded indemnity program to compensate persons subject  to
unreasonable administrative enforcement  is  probably  not warranted.
This is primarily because there  is  no  evidence that  unreasonable
enforcement exists on more than  a very infrequent basis,  and  because
EPA's current enforcement policies  make  such occurrences  unlikely.
However,  it cannot be stated with certainty that  unreasonable adminis-
trative enforcement will not occur.

    The most effective approach  toward resolving  potential  problems of
unreasonable enforcement would be to ensure the availability  of  judi-
cial review (to the extent it is not already available) in  cases  where
the Agency has clearly engaged in abusive or erroneous  activity.  This
would preserve existing compliance  incentives  on  the part of  the
affected  industry (and Incentives to take precautions against agency
errors), and it would preserve existing  enforcement  Incentives on the
part of the Agency at a time when there  is  little evidence  of agency
abuse and substantial evidence of agency restraint.   Any  new  indemni-
fication program should be established only when  a pattern  of error
and abuse is clearly discernible, and  it is apparent that alternative
loss avoidance mechanisms are inadequate.
                                 -147-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
                     G.   CHANGES IN AGENCY POLICY

 1.   Description of the  Problem

     Stability and predictability of government action is Important to
 regulated parties.  Abrupt or unexpected changes in government policy
 can disrupt planning and cause losses beyond those attributable to the
 new policy itself.  Furthermore, since an industry is rarely homo-
 geneous,  a change in policy can affect the relative competitive posi-
 tions  in  ways that may  not be intended or even foreseen by the Agency.
 While  the usual effect  of a change of policy often times is much the
 same as the effect of an original policy (i.e., the cost of complying
 with a justified governmental regulation), the issue Is a topic of
 considerable concern to Industry and some academics, and has been
 raised in so many of our discussions that it must be addressed.
 Nevertheless, we did not find, and none of our contacts brought to our
 attention,  any actual case of a change in policy causing a loss that
 might  justify indemnification.

     There are two theoretical fact patterns that bear discussion.  The
 first  is  a  situation in which a company must comply with a new or
 changed regulation at the same time that it is challenging the regula-
 tion in administrative  or judicial review.  Although a prevailing
 party  may be able to collect court costs and attorney's fees, no sta-
 tute would  entitle it to reimbursement for the costs of Interim
 compliance  with a regulation which is later overturned.  The second
 situation need not Involve an erroneous or arbitrary change in policy.
 It  might  happen that even a fully justified change could impose an
 unreasonable cost on a  segment of the industry.  For example, suppose
 that the  Agency changed from a relatively more stringent standard to a
 relatively  less stringent standard for emissions.   Those who had
 acquired  equipment or otherwise invested to comply with the first
 standard  might well find that the investment was lost.  Thus, those
 who  had been most diligent in complying would have the greatest loss.
 This might  also happen  as standards become more stringent, if equip-
ment used to meet the old standard would not work for the new one.

 2.   Evaluation

     Although immunity of the government and its officers has been
 steadily  strinking over the last  forty years, there are still some
 core activities protected from tort liability.   Broad decisions to
adopt  particular  standards or regulations or other decisions calling
 for  balance  of  policy considerations are discretionary judgments
within the  exemption from the Federal Tort Claims  Act.8*  The reasons
 for  protecting  such policy decisions go to the very structure of our
government:   maintaining the independence of the three branches.  It
 is not the  proper role  of the judiciary to remake  the decisions of the
executive.   Political questions  are not considered amenable to testing
 through tort  law  because "objective standards are  notably lacking when
                                 -148-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATON STUDY
                                             Section IV
 the question Is not negligence but social wisdom, not due care but
 political practicability,  not  reasonableness but economic exped-
 iency. "1" Changes in policy are by definition part of this category of
 protected government activity.  Thus,  any recommendation for Indem-
 nification In this area either has to  overcome a heavy presumption
 against  it,  or find a way  around the separation of powers problem.

     The  factors for analysis that were identified in Section III are
 useful  in evaluating the potential Inderaniflability of losses caused
 by  changes in policy.

     Alternatives to indemnification can be used to reduce or spread
 any cost  of  changes in regulation.  Advance notice and phased-in
 compliance can allow those involved to make an orderly transition.
 Participation of a representative sample of all firms in an industry
 during rulemaking could help avoid unwitting impacts on competitive
 relationships that might result if the Agency did not understand all
 the variations in the industry.  Exceptions and waivers can permit
 flexibility  in application of  the new  regulation to individual
 situations.   Most of the statutes administered by EPA have some relief
 by  means  of  variance or exception for  small businesses or those to
 whom the  regulation was unfairly applied.  Of course, some costs will
 remain no matter how long  the  transition period, or flexible the
 implementation.   Whether these are beyond the cost of compliance can
 only be determined from an examination of the particular facts of a
 specific  situation.

     Another  powerful alternative to indemnification for changes in
 policy is review of  the decision by administrative or judicial
 tribunals.   The  remedy sought  is not money damages but modification or
 retraction of the offending policy action.  This may explain, in part,
 why we found  so  few actual losses connected to changing policies.  If
 a projected  loss  really is severe or unreasonably allocated, it can
 often be  prevented by obtaining a stay of the action while the review
 is  ongoing.

     An abrupt change might constitute  a procedural inequity, if made
 in  the absence  of compelling public health reasons,  but the government
 rarely acts  abruptly.   Even the emergency decision to cancel some uses
 of  pesticides containing 2,4,5-T and Sllvex came at  the end of eight
 years of  regulatory  action and study,  Including an earlier can-
 cellation of  home and aquatic  uses of  2,4,5-T (later withdrawn).
 Though the manufacturers of the pesticides were surely aware of the
 continuing Agency concern  and  new developments in the scientific
 understanding, and thus  the potential  for regulation, it is possible
 that the  sellers  and users of  the pesticides were not prepared.  This
 points up  a  possible substantive inequity:   that cost of the govern-
ment action might  fall  most heavily on those least responsible, and
 least able to  bear It.   This would depend upon an analysis of the
 case.  Since  a ban is  the  most drastic action the Agency can take, the
more common and  less onerous actions would have less severe impacts.
                                 -149-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATON STUDY
                                             Section IV
    Changes  In policy  are  often based on explicit Congressional
direction.   Either  the law itself  is amended, or the law specifies
that  the  Agency must revise  standards in light of new knowledge.  In
the face  of  such  clear directions,  it would be difficult to justify
indemnification if  Congress  has not already authorized it.  Occasion-
ally  the  question of compensation  is addressed directly*  After the
de-regulation  of  the trucking  industry,  the tax code was amended to
allow deductions  for the book,  value of trucking certificates rendered
useless by the de-regulation.   This only partially compensated those
who had held the  certificates  for  a long time and those whose taxes
were  low.  This treatment  indicated that Congress regarded the loss as
a cost of doing business rather than an  extraordinary loss.

    The ability of  the Ageiccy  to balance policy considerations objec-
tively could be hampered significantly by the possibility of having to
pay for the costs.  This is  one of  the reasons for exempting policy
decisions from the  Federal Tort Claims Act.  If, however, Congress
should decide  that  the cost  of  some change in policy ought to be born
by the taxpayers  rather than by some segment of the regulated
industry, this is a different matter.  It would be a political deci-
sion  by those  most  accountable,  and would be separate from the policy
decision of how best to implement a statute.

3.  Conclusion

    Change in  policy is a category  almost as broad as all Agency
action, and it  is difficult  to  make generalizations about it.
However, it is  clear that for most  changes there is no extraordinary
loss  suffered.  The alternatives to indemnification work well here,
either to avoid the loss through participation in the creation of the
decision to change  by  exemption, or by judicial review and modifica-
tion of the policy.
                                 -150-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
                        FOOTNOTES TO SECTION IV

            surveys and  reports reviewed were the following:  ERT, "The
 Effects of the Clean Air Act on Industrial Planning and Development"
 (for the Business  Roundtable); Vice President Bush's Regulatory Relief
 Task Force survey  and responses; The Small Business Hotline.

     ^This was  not  a thorough or scientifically designed survey of all
 industries that  deal with EPA.  Instead,  it was a series of informal
 conversations  in which  we attempted to  ascertain thoughts about indem-
 nification and to  learn about losses that the agency might have
 caused.   The first conversations were quite general.  As we reached
 people  who were  knowledgable about  a particular event, or Interested
 in  a particular  area they became more specific.  Often, persons with
 whom we spoke  were not  willing to commit  their firms or organizations
 to  particular  positions;  and many requested that they not be quoted by
 name.   At this writing  several persons  have Indicated interest in a
 further opportunity to  provide input after reviewing a written report.

     ^Three Freedom of Information Act (FOIA) bills are before the
 Congress.  The Reagan Administration bill is H.R.  4805 and S. 1751.
 Senator Orrin  Hatch (R.-Utah)  has introduced S. 1730, which is similar
 to  the  Administration bill.   S.  1730 has  been approved by the Senate
 Subcommittee on  the Constitution and, as  of May 19,  1982, was still in
 markup  before  the  Senate  Judiciary  Committee.   According to a tele-
 phone conversation on March  22,  1982, with Mr.  Randy Radar, subcom-
 mittee  staff person,  the  focus of S.  1730 is on defining what is and
 what  is  not confidential  business information under  the FOIA.  Because
 it  is felt  that  the current  law does  not  clearly define confidential
 business  information, the  subcommittee  has attempted to develop more
 reliable  standards  for  this  determination.   The definition of CBI
 would affect what  can and  cannot be  disclosed  under  the FOIA.

    4H.R.  5203,  The Federal  Insecticide,  Fungicide,  and Rodentlcide Act
 Amendments of  1982,  was  reported out  of the House  Agriculture Commit-
 tee on May 17, 1982.

    5Id.  under Section  5(7)  a   new  subsection  (h)  entitled "Civil
ActiorT^would  be added  to  §  10 of FIFRA.   Additionally, section 7 of
H.R. 5203 would  amend §  14(b)(3)  to  provide criminal penalties to pri-
vate parties and federal employees  and  contractors for unauthorized
knowing or willful  disclosure.

    6E.g., Chevron  Chemical  Co.  v. Costle.  641  F.2d  104 (3d Cir.
 1981), cert, denied,  101 S.  Ct.  3110  (1981)  (concerning §§ 3(c)(l)(D)
and 10 of FIFRA); Mobay v. Costle,  517 F.  Supp. 252  (W.D. Pa. 1981),
which expressly  followed  the holding  of the Chevron  case; Union
Carbide Agricultural Products  Co. v. Gorsuch,  (S.D.N.Y..,  No.  76 Civ.
2913) (preliminary  injunction  against EPA issued by  the district court
vacated on appeal by  the Second  Circuit);  and  Petrolite Corp. v. EPA,
                                 -151-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATON STUDY
                                             Section IV
 519 F. Supp. 966 (D.D.C. 1981) (EPA's motion for summary judgment
 granted).

     Due to the erroneous FOIA release of an EPA review of data on
 Monsanto's herbicide glyphosate in May 1982, the Agency in August 1982
 agreed to  special procedures designed to protect Monsanto's interests.
 Specifically,  any future requests for registration of herbicides con-
 taining active ingredients will be submitted to EPA's Scientific
 Advisory Panel for a judgment whether the application is based upon
 Monsanto data  improperly disclosed by the Agency.  The new procedures
 to which EPA agreed were set forth in a court judgment issued by the
 U.S.  District  Court for the Eastern District of Missouri, Monsanto v.
 Gorsuch, No. 79-0366-0(1).  See "Current Developments" at 758, BNA
 Environment Reporter (Oct. 1, 1982).
 ^^^^^^••^^•^•••^^••••^•^H^^MKH^HM^^H           k

    7Telephone conversation on March 22, 1982 with James Nelson, EPA
 Office of  General Counsel.
     °See TSCA Legislative history on CBI issue.
     Q
     E.g.,  U.S.  Environmental Protection Agency,  TSCA Confidentla
Business Information Security Manual (Office of  Toxic Substances,
October 1981).
     10TSCA  §  14(d)  contains  a misdemeanor provision which applies to
any  current or  former  United States employee,  officer or contractor.
FIFRA  §  10(f) contains a  similar  provision.   RCRA § 3007(b)(2)  and
CERCLA §  104(e)(2)(B)  contain criminal sanctions applying to any per-
son  (such as  a  state official) not  subject to  18 U.S.C.  § 1905.

     HTelephone conversation on March 8,  1982  with Mr. James T.
O'Reilly, lecturer  in  law at the  University  of Cincinnati and senior
counsel  for Proctor and Gamble Co.   O'Reilly was particularly con-
cerned about  the progressive nature of employee discipline sanctions
and  the  fact  that the  removal sanction is not  usually applied until
the  third offense.  It should be  noted,  however, that "in unusual cir-
cumstances  greater  or  lesser penalties may be  applied unless otherwise
provided  by law."   TSCA Security  Manual,  supra note 9 at 31 (Appendix
I).

     12Id.   O'Reilly argued that non-use  of 18  U.S.C. § 1905 Is  indica-
tive of  its lack of deterrent effect.   Also, he noted that § 9-2.025
of the U.S. Attorney's Manual dated May  1979 requires that any  prose-
cutions under §  1905 must be cleared by  Department of Justice offi-
cials  in Washington, D.C.  O'Reilly contended  that this  restricts the
use  of §  1905.   An  attorney  at the  Department  of Justice, however,
emphasized  that  there  is  no  policy  not to use  § 1905 and that the U.S.
Attorney's  Manual provision  is informationally oriented  and probably
designed  to permit  national  coordination  on  the use of § 1905.   Tele-
phone conversation  on  March  10, 1982 with Mr.  Frederick  Hess, Acting
                                 -152-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATON STUDY
                                             Section IV
 Director of Legal  Support  Services  (dealing with FOIA Matters),  U.S.
 Department of Justice.   Another Justice Department attorney felt that
 it  would be speculative  to conclude that use of  § 1905 would be
 restricted because of  the  U.S.  Attorney's Manual requirement.  Tele-
 phone conversation on March 10, 1982 with Mr.  Alan Carvtr,  Public
 Integrity Section  (handling 18  U.S.C. § 1905), U.S. Department of
 Justice.

     ^Telephone  conversations on February 25,  1982 with Mr. Charles
 Breece,  EPA Office of General Counsel;  on March  2 and 22,  1982 with
 Mr.  James Nelson,  EPA Office of General Counsel; on March  22,  1982
 with Mr. John Euller, Assistant Director, Civil  Division,  U.S.
 Department of Justice; and on March 22,  1982 with Mr. James Klapps,
 Torts Section, Civil Division,  U.S.  Department of Justice.
                                  c
       Id.  Nelson,  Hess,  and Carver;  and telephone conversations  on
 March TT7 1982 with Mr.  Larry Swales, Security Officer,  EPA Office of
 Toxic Substances;  and on March  23,  1982 with Mr. James Conn, Divi-
 sional Office for  the Mid-Atlantic  Region,  EPA Inspector General's
 Office.   The  only  known  Intentional  unauthorized disclosure of CBI may
 have occurred in the area  of EPA contractors voluntarily submitting
 information needed for the competitive  bidding process.  Apparently,
 EPA  employees may  have disclosed information to  a contractor's compe-
 titor.   In response to "blistering"  letters received from  irate  con-
 tractors,  EPA has  undertaken careful investigations to determine
 whether  criminal prosecution might  be warranted.  So far,  the  evidence
 has  been insufficient to warrant criminal prosecution,  although  cer-
 tain cases  have  in the past been referred to the Department of Justice
 for  consideration.  Conn,  id.

     150'Reilly,  supra note 11.   Mr.  O'Reilly claims that instances of
 disclosure  and loss have occurred and that  such  incidents  have been
 described  to  him "off the  record" by affected  parties.
    17<
          example, H.R. 5203, supra note A, permits  limited  disclosure
of health and safety test data to environmental  groups,  but  then  pro-
vides for substantial civil liability if that  information  is then
passed on improperly to a competitor of the party whose  CBI  is
disclosed.
         example of statutory authorization where  this  problem might
arise is found under TSCA § 14(a)(3) which permits disclosure "if  the
Administrator determines it necessary to protect health or  the
environment against an unreasonable risk of injury to health or  the
enviornment."  This provision, however, has not yet  been used.
                                 -153-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATON STUDY
                                             Section IV
     20Jayson,  Handling  Federal Tort Claims § 260.06 (Matthew Bender,
 1964 and  current  supplements)  states at 13-96:

                   The  breadth of  Section 2680(h)'s exclu-
               sion of "any claim arising out of * * * inter-
               ference with contract rights" is  unclear
               largely because  the  common-law concept of  the
               tort of Interference with contract rights  is
               not a  clear-cut  one.  Interference with
               contract  rights  may  be but one aspect of tor-
               tious  conduct In the field of economic
               relations.   The  broader concept includes a
               variety of  torts and improper conduct
               comprising  the body  of law loosely described
               as  interference  with business relations.  The
               Restatement  of Torts, in discussing this
               general area,  deals  with such subjects as
               engaging  in  business for the purpose of
               causing loss of  business to another, fraudu-
               lent marketing,  trademark infringement,
               disclosure of  trade  secrets, refusal to deal
               with another,  inducing breach of  contract  or
               refusal to deal,  and labor disputes, to men-
               tion but  a few.

                   Whether any or  all of these  other,
               closely related  torts are also embraced within
               the Tort  Claims  Act  phrase "interference with
               contract  rights"  is  still unsettled.  The
               legislative  history  of Section 2680(h)  provi-
               des no answer.   Prosser states that there  is a
               definitely marked  out tort "under the name of
               inducing  breach  of contract, or interference
              with contract."  And\the Restatement sets  out
               a general principle  of liability  under  the
              heading "inducing  breach of contract or refu-
               sal to deal."  It  should be noted,  however,
               that the  phrase  used In the Tort  Claims Act  is
              not precisely  the  same as that used by  those
               two leading  works  on torts,  (emphasis  added).

    The FTCA's exclusion of  claims arising out  of "interference with
contract rights" is susceptible  of covering not only  interference with
existing contractual relations but also interference  with  precontrac-
tual relations or prospective  advantage.   There has been a lack of
unanimity among the cases  on this  question.   Dupree v. United States,
264 F.2d 140 (3d Cir. 1959), a case involving the alleged  negligent
withholding of a security  clearance by the Coast  Guard,  held that the
exception covers interference with prospective  advantage,  as well as
existing contractual relations.  But the Ninth  Circuit in  Builders
                                 -154-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATON STUDY
                                             Section IV
 Corp.  of America v.  United States,  U8 F.  Supp. 482 (N.D.  Cal. 1957)
 rev'd,  259 F.2d 766, 769 (9th Cir.  1958),  indicated doubt  about this
 conclusion.   See also Black v.  United States,  389 F. Supp. 529 (D.D.C.
 1975),  appeal sub,  nom,  Black v.  Sheraton  Corp. of America, 564 F.2d
 531,  540-41  (D.C. Cir.  1977), In  which the Court of Appeals expressly
 rejected the government's contention that  the  interference with
 contract exception was  applicable in a case Involving invasion of pri-
 vacy  and the dissemination of information  to the effect that the
 claimant was connected  with organized crime.  Another relevant case is
 Quinones v.  United  States,  492  F.2d 1269  (3d Cir. 1974), in which a
 former  government employee was  allowed to  bring an action  under the
 FTCA based on the alleged failure of the government to use due care in
 maintaining  his personnel records,  resulting in damage to  his reputa-
 tion.   In both Black and Quinones the courts refused to stretch excep-
 tion  (h) beyond its  specific coverage and  allowed the claimants to
 maintain their causes of action.

    2^0'Reilly,  supra note 11,  noted in particular that tort law in
 the District of Columbia is not highly developed.  He also thought
 that proof of the quantum of damages would be  particularly difficult.
    22
      Supra note  19.
        primary  reason  for expressly  subjecting  the  government  to  suit
for either negligent  or intentional unauthorized disclosures  would be
to affect agency behavior by  prompting  it  to  be  more careful  in its
handling of CBI.  With  regard to  criminal  sanctions, the  burden of
proof is much higher  and so the impact  on  the agency and  its  employees
may be less with criminal sanctions than with civil  tort  liability.
The product liability area is frequently cited as one in  which  tort
liability may significantly affect behavior and  prompt more careful
actions.  Telephone conversation  on May 19, 1982 with Dr.  Nickolas
Ashford, Center  for Policy Alternatives, Massachusetts Institute of
Technology.
          example, one such general problem may  be  the  lack of  a
requirement in FOIA that notice be given  to an information  submitter
prior to its release by an Agency.  O'Reilly, supra note  11,  discussed
this problem with regard to the FDA in his testimony on July 16,  1981
at Freedom of Information Act oversight hearings before a subcommittee
of the House Government Operations Committee.  See  hearings at  596,
599, 609-10.

            note 6.

    26Environmental Defense Fund, Inc. v. Goreuch,  17 E.R.C.  1099
(D.D.C. 1982).  EPA was ordered to notice the proposed  National
Contingency Plan revisions within 30 days from the  date of  the  court's
order on February 12, 1982.  EPA met this requirement on  March  12,
1982 (47 Fed. Reg. 10472).  The public comment period closed April 28,
                                 -155-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATON STUDY
                                             Section IV
 1982  and  EPA  now  has  until  July  16th to publish the revised  National
 Contingency Plan.   See  also NRDC,  Inc.  v.  Train,  510 F.2d 692  (D.C.
 Cir.  1975)  (action  to compel publication of effluent limitation guide-
 lines  under the Federal  Water Pollution Control Act).

    27gee, e.g.,  the  EPA Office  of Policy  & Resource Management cata-
 loging"^? of  September  1, 1981 of  industry responses to V'ice President
 Bush's  letter to  Industry groups soliciting comments to the  Cabinet-
 Level Task Force  on Regulatory Relief,  especially at A-7, p. 2
 (Prevention of Significant  Deterioration — Set I Pollutants:   recom-
 mendation of  mandatory  deadlines In dealing with applications  and
 reviews); at  B-5, pp. 1-2 (NPDES and Consolidated Permits Programs:
 claims  that "regulations placed  great and  unjustified  burdens  on
 industry  with specific  concerns  about delays in processing applica-
 tions and issuing permits;  recommendation  to revise regulations to
 establish reasonable  time limits within which the entire permitting
 process must  operate; recommendation to have government agencies work
 together  to streamline  permitting  functions);  at  B-9 (Construction
 Grants:   recommendation  tthat states should be delegated full  review
 responsibility because  EPA  review  of every stage  of project  causes
 extensive paperwork and  delay; and at E, pp. 4-5  (Pesticide  Programs
 Under FIFRA:   recommendation to  establish  procedures for reviewing
 data more quickly in  the pesticide registration process, with  specific
 deadlines for review  and conditional granting of  registration  if EPA
 does not  meet the deadline).  See  also  the Business Roundtable report,
 infra note 31.

    28M.  Hamilton,  "The  Permit Explosion:   Siting New  Energy Facil-
 ities In  the  Western  United  States," (Dep't of Political Science,
 Colorado  State University,  Ft. Collins,  Colorado;  Presented  to the
 State Energy  Permitting  Workshop of the Western Governor's Policy
 Office and the New  Mexico Dep't  of Energy  & Minerals,  Albequerque,
 N.M.; Dec. 16-17, 1980).

    See also  Urban  Systems  Research & Engineering, Inc., "Causes of
 Delay for Major Industrial  Projects," (Draft Final Report prepared for
 the Council on Environmental  Quality, Jan. 11, 1981),  which  reviewed
 the existing  literature  and  attempted to provide  a more comprehensive
 look at the effects of  regulations on project schedules than had been
 done by previous studies.   The Urban Systems analysis  involved 41 case
 studies of non-nuclear energy projects  and non-energy  projects. In
 over half of  the cases,  project  delays  were attributable to  a  variety
 of factors.   The remaining  cases "were  equally divided between cases
where regulatory factors alone were responsible for the delays and
cases where economic  factors  alone were  responsible.  The availability
of labor  and  equipment was  not a significant cause of  delay.  The
study concluded that  "while  the  regulatory delays  can  to some  extent
be managed (and minimized),  they are often out weighed by economic
difficulties  which  are external  to the  project management."
                                 -156-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
           memorandum  entitled  "Briefing on Permitting,  9/1/81"  from
 Stuart  Sessions,  Chief  Energy  Facilities Branch,  Office of Policy
 Analysis,  OPRM  to Nolan Clark,  Associate Administrator  for Policy &
 Resource Management.  More  current  information provided by Mr.
 Sessions as  of  April  30,  1982  indicated from a sample of 28% of the
 recently Issued PSD permits that  the  average time from  the application
 submittal  to permit issuance was  10.5 months and  from the time  of sub-
 mission of the  last information to  permit Issuance was  4.9 months.   It
 was  noted  that  the submission  of  the  last information is often  later
 than when  the application is declared by EPA to be complete. Thus,
 "the most  complex permit  processing takes less than a year." Infra
 note 30.

     •^Telephone conversation on March 12,  1982 and interview on April
 27,  1982 with Mr.  Stuart  Sessions, e Chief ,  EPA Energy Facilities
 Branch, Office  of Policy  Analysis,  OPRM.  In 1980, EPA  established  a
 specific branch in the  Office  of  Policy Analysis  for the purpose of
 evaluating possible improvements  to the permit-processing system.
 See  also text accompanying  note 32  infra.

     ^Environmental Research &  Technology,  Inc.,  I & II Effects of  the
 Clean Air  Act on  Industrial Planning  & Development;   Analysis of Case
 Studies (The Business Roundtable  Air  Quality Project) (July 1981).
 See  also EPA memorandum entitled  "Review of  BRT Report  on 'Effects  of
 the  Clean  Air Act on  Industrial Planning & Development," from Stuart
 Sessions,  Chief Energy  Facilities Branch,  Office  of Policy Analysis,
 OPRM to Kathleen  Bennett, Assistant Administrator for Air,  Noise &
 Radiation  (Oct. 27, 1981).

     32Supra  note  30.

     33Supra  note  30 and note 29,  at 5-6.
          has established a work group  to conduct an Agency-wide eval-
uation of whether or not various fees might be appropriately  levied.
A report is anticipated by mid-summer 1982.  Supra  note 30.

    ^Although § 165(c) of the Clean Air Act contains a mandatory
requirement that PSD permits "shall be  granted or denied not  later
than one year after the date of filing  of [a] completed application,"
no mandamus action has ever been brought to force Agency action on a
PSD permit application.  Nevertheless,  such an action could be
brought.  Interview on June 2, 1982 with Mr. Peter  Wyckoff, EPA Office
of General Counsel (Handling PSD Permits).

    36Appendix B, note 54.

    37Appendix A, page A-20.

    ™U.S. General Accounting Office, Gaines & Shortcomings in
Resolving Regulatory Conflicts & Overlaps, Report to the Congress by
                                 -157-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section IV
 the  Comptroller General  of  the  United  Stated  (PAD-81-76;  June  23,
 1981).

     39Id.  at  58.

     40Id.  at  60-68.

     41Id.  at  68-79.

     42Id.  at  44.

     ^Description generally  based on Rendleman,  "Legal  Anatomy of  an
Air  Pollution Emergency," 2  Environmental Affairs  (Boston College)  90
(1972); and Hardy, Pate, ejt  al^, "First Use of  the Federal Clean Air
Act's Emergency Authority, "A Local Analysis,1"  64 Amer.  J. Public
Health 72  (1974).

     44Hardy,  Pate, id. at 74.

     45United  States v. U.S.  Steel. CA  71-1041 (N.D. Ala.,  Nov.  19,
1971), Transcript of Hearing before Judge Pointer,  quoted  in
Rendleman, id.  at 100.

     ^Telephone conversation with Fournier J. Gale, III,  on January
28,  1982.

     A7H.R. Rep. No. 90-728 at 19; S. Rep. No. 91-1196,  91st Cong., 2d
Sess. (1970).
           an air alert was declared the following June, all regula-
tions and phased curtailment plans were in place.  Inspections showed
that sources were complying with the plans, and  that the particulate
count decreased markedly when the abatement plans went into effect.
Hardy, Pate, id. at 76.

    48aTelephone conversation on May 25, 1982 with Jeff Miller, former
EPA Acting Assistant Administrator for Enforcement.

    48bTelepnone conversation on May 26, 1982 with Pamela John in
Contracts Management Division of EPA.

          discussion supra at 66-71.
          discussion of enforcement discretion in City of Seabrook v.
Costle, 16 E.R.C. 1676 (5th Cir. 1981).
           detailed description of current and planned enforcement
activities may be found in prepared materials supporting the Adminis-
                                 -158-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATON STUDY
                                             Section IV
 trations budget  proposal for F.Y.  1982 and 1983.   The F.Y. 1982
 materials have been  reprinted in an abbreviated form in SNA:
 Environment  Reporter,  Federal Laws  51:1601-16-45.   The F.Y. 1983
 materials are  available  at  EPA in  an unclassified publication
 entitled, "Justification of Appropriation Estimates for Committee on
 Appropriation, Fiscal  Year  1983."
           boundaries  of  protection relating to inspections and other
 investigations  are  well  established under the Fourth Amendment.  See,
 e ; g . ,  Public  Service  Company  of  Indiana  v.  EPA,  15 E.R.C. 1939 (S.D.
 Ind.  1981); EPA's inspection  policy as stated In a memorandum to the
 Regional Administrators  from  the Assistant  Administrator for Enforce-
 ment  on  "Conduct of Inspections  After  the Barlow's Decision" (April
 11,  1979),  reprinted  in  BNA:   Environmental Reporter, Federal Laws
 41:2451.   Restrictions also exist in the individual pollution control
 statutes and  under  the Federal Torts Claims Act.  While Agency inspec-
 tions  may  sometimes be inconvenient and  occasionally cause injury, to
 the  extent  that these impacts  are unjustifiable, they may normally be
 avoided by  court action.  To  the extent  that the inspection results
 may  be erroneous, EPA must enforce on  the basis  of the erroneous
 results before  any  actual Injury would occur —thus, it is the enfor-
 cement action,,  rather than the inspection,  that  merits primary concern
 in the current  study.
          authority may be express or  implied.   In  general,  the agency
provides notice of a violation prior to  issuing  an  abatement order or
proceeding to litigation even when the statute does not require such
notice.

    55See also §§ 26 and 27 of the Federal Insecticide, Fungicide and
Rodenticide Act.

    56See, e.g., § 113 of the Clean Air  Act  and  § 309  of the Clean
Water Act.

    57See, e.g., § 120 of the Clean Air  Act.

            note 52; see also blacklisting procedures  stated in 40
     SuPra note •>*;  see also blaclc;
.F.R. §§ 1520 et seq.,  Appendix A.
C	

    5"in the recent administration's budget  proposal,  EPA indicated
: .at the pesticides enforcement program would  shift  in emphasis  to
compliance assistance to both industry and the  states.  EPA  document
entitled "Environmental Protection Agency, Justification of  Appropria-
tion Estimates for Committee on Appropriation,  Fiscal  Year 1983" at
P-48-49.  This is consistent with §§ 26 and  27, which  provide  the
States with primary enforcement responsibilities.

    60Id. at A-110-111; WQ-114; DW-49; under the toxics and  Superfund
legislation there is no statutory analog to  the State  implementation
and delegation programs that exist under other  statutes.
                                 -159-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATON  STUDY
                                             Section IV
     "^•Memorandum  to  Regional  Administrators  from  Kathleen  Bennett
 (December  29,  1981).   Delegation  to  the  states  is the  Administrator's
 top  priority management  goal  for  F.Y.  1982.   "Adminstrator's  Manage-
 ment  Goals for  F.Y.  1982,"  reprinted  in  Senate  Oversight Hearing,
 October  15, 1981,  No.  97-H29,  97th Cong.,  1st Sess., at 85.

    62See  Testimony  of Administrator  Gorsuch, Senate Oversight
 Hearing, October  15, 1981,  No.  97-H29, 97th  Cong.,  1st Sess.  at  34.
    63
    64
Bennett memorandum, supra note 61.

Id.  See also draft memorandum from EPA Administrator Anne M.
Gorsuch on General Operating Procedures  for  Civil  Enforcement  Program,
reprinted in BNA:  Environment  Reporter,  Current Developments  (May  21,
1982) at 78, 82.               0
      See £NA:  Environment Reporter, Current Developments  (May  14,
1982) at 38.

    ^Senate Oversight Hearing supra note 62 at 33.

    "'A substantial effort is underway  to design and  implement self-
auditing programs within  the various regulatory media.   Interview with
Karen Blumenfeld, Regulation Reform Branch, Office of Policy and
Resource Management, EPA.  See also proposed self-certification  rules
for PCB generators, proposed amendment  to 40 C.F.R. part 761,
§ 761.185, 47 Fed. Reg. 24976-88  (June  8, 1982).

    68See discussion supra, Section III note 117.

    "'Gorsuch Draft Memorandum, § VI, supra note 64.

    70EPA concurrence procedures  have undergone several  changes  during
the past year.  See Memoranda from Enforcement Counsel to Regional
Administrators (December  29, 1981 and February 26, 1982); Gorsuch
Draft Memorandum, supra note 64.  As currently stated, these proce-
dures provide headquarters offices with the principal role  in defining
national enforcement policy, but  give the Regional Offices  the primary
decision-making authority regarding .the Initiation of administrative
action; no headquarters concurrence is  normally required for such
actions unless a new issue of national  policy is raised.  This rule is
not absolute, however.  Variations exist among the different programs,
depending on prior guidance (and  the need to maintain active headquar-
ters supervision).  For example,  procedures involving enforcement of
RCRA and CERCLA provide for headquarters participation in most aspects
of administrative enforcement activity  involving inactive sites —
from the listing of priority sites to the issuance of administrative
orders.  See Gorsuch Draft Memorandum § IV supra note 64, at 82;
Memorandum to Regional Administrators from Chlstopher J. Capper and
William A. Sullivan, Jr.  (February 23,  1982) at 8.
                                 -160-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATON  STUDY
                                             Section  IV
     ^Senate  Oversight Hearing,  supra  note  62,  at  11-32.

     72See  EPA Budget, supra note  59, at  A-113,  114,  117;  1-27,  28,  31;
SF-24,  25,  29-30,  55.  The most  substantial  reductions would  occur  in
stationary air (A-106-107); water quality (WQ-109-110); hazardous
waste  (HW-59-60);  pesticides (P-44-45) and  toxic substances (TS-48-49).
Although the  drinking water enforcement  program would not  experience
reductions  of the  same degree, it is already  funded  at a  comparatively
low  level —  less  than 2% of the  overall enforcement budget.  Only  in
the  areas  of  mobile air pollution, improper waste  disposal and  hazard-
ous  substance response are increases anticipated.

     Current resolutions from both the House and Senate Budget Commit-
tees would maintain the F.Y. 1983 enforcement budget authority  at
approximately the  same level as F.Y. 1982.  See S. Con. Res. 92; H.
Con. Res. 345.  However, Congress is only part  of  the way  through the
budget  process and has yet to reach agreement on an  overall F.Y. 1983
budget  or  to  consider what spending ceilings  should  be imposed.  It
should  be noted, moreover, that the Executive Branch has  formal as
well as informal options for decreasing actual  expenditures, regard-
less of what  is finally approved by Congress.   Under the  Congressional
Budget  Act, 31 U.S.C. §§ 1301 et seq., the Administration may rescind
a portion of  the budget (subject  to congressional  approval), or defer
a portion (subject to congressional disapproval).  Informally,  the
executive office traditionally exercises its  discretion in committing
funds to suit  actual circumstances.  As a practical matter, Congress
must rely on  specific legislative directives  and oversight proceedings
(as well as informal pressure) to ensure that its  objectives are
achieved.

     '•'Research included the following sources:

        1.     Complaints received in response  to Vice President Bush
              letter of March 25, 1981, regarding the need for regula-
              tory relief.

        2.    Review of complaints raised by the Business Roundtable in
              its reports entitled The Business Roundtable, Air Quality
             Project, "Effects of the Clean Air Act on Industrial
             Planning and Development," Vols. 1 and 2 (July 1981).

        3.    Consultation with industry associations identified in
             Appendix C to this report.

        4.    Congressional Oversight Hearings:  House Report,
             "Implementation of the Federal Water Pollution Control
             Act,"  No. 96-71,  96th Cong. 2d Sess. (December 1980);
             Senate Hearing, "Environmental Protection Agency Over-
             sight," No.  97-H29,  97th Cong.  1st Sess. (October 15,
             1981); Senate Hearings, "Implementation of the Comprehen-
                                 -161-

-------
                                             LNDEMNIFICATON STUDY
                                             Section IV
              sive Environmental  Response,  Compensation,  and  Liability
              Act  of  1981,"  No.  97-H-31,  97th Cong.  1st Sess. (July 8
              and  20,  1981);  Senate Hearings, "Oversight  of  Hazardous
              Waste Management  and  the Resource  Conservation  and
              Recovery Act,"  (unnumbered  publication)  96th Cong.  1st
              Sess. (July  19  and  August 1,  1979);  House Hearings,
              "Oversight — Clean Air Act Amendments of 1977,"  No.
              96-110,  96th Cong.  1st Sess.  (July 30, November 27  and
              28,  1979); Senate Hearings  "Clean  Mr  Act Oversight," No.
              97-H12,  97th Cong.  1st Sess.  (April  8, 9, May  20, June 2,
              3, 4, 5,  9,  11, 22, 23,  24, 25, July 8 and  9,  1981);
              Senate Hearings,  "Toxic  Substances Control  Act  Over-
              sight,"  No.  95-H69, 95th Cong., 2d Sess.  (July  20,  21,
              1978); House Hearings, "Authorization  and Oversight of
              the  Toxic Substances  Control  Act," No. 96-28, 96th  Cong.
              1st  Sess. (March 8, 13,  20, 1979); Index  to Publications
              of the United States  Congress,  1978-1982, Congressional
              Information  Service,  Washington, D.C.

         5.    Report of the National Commission  on Air  Quality, "To
              Breathe  Clean Air," March 1981.

    '^George  Freeman,  attorney for Hunton  and Williams of Richmond,
Virginia, and counsel  to  numerous  facilities subject to  EPA  air  pollu-
tion  regulations,  discussed  three  enforcement cases that he  described
as evidence of unreasonable  EPA  enforcement  policies.  All three
involved EPA's use of  prosecutorial discretion  in a manner  that
resulted in significant burdens  on the facilities affected.   In a
later conversation, Freeman  indicated  that while  he though EPA's
stance  to be  unnecessary, it was not  wholly  without legal support and
he felt  the primary problem  exists in  the  1977  Clean Air Amendments.
Senate Oversight Hearings, June  4,  1981, part 2,  No. 97-H12, 97th
Cong.,  1st Sess. at 479-82.  Interview with  George  Freeman,  July 9,
1982.

     ^Environmental Protection Agency, Senate Oversight  Hearing
(October 15,  1981) No. 97-H29, 97th Cong., 1st  Sess. 1-11; Senate
Hearings on Implementation of CERCLA  (July 8 and  20, 1981),  No.
97-H31, 97th  Cong., 1st Sess.; House Oversight  Report  on Clean Water
Act, No. 96-71, 96th Cong.,  2d Sess. (December  1980) 53-54;  Senate
Oversight on  Resource Conservation and Recovery Act (unnumbered) (July
19 and August 1, 1979) 96th  Cong.,  1st Sess. 317-622.

          also report of  the National  Commission  on Air  Quality, "To
Breathe Clean Air" (March 1981) at 3.8-14; BNA:  Environment Reporter,
Current Developments (July 24, 1981) at 414; House Hearings, Health
Standards for Air Pollutants, No. 97-97, 97th Cong., 1st Sess.
(October 14 and 15, 1981); House Hearings, Clean Air Act Part 1, No.
97-102, 97th Cong. 1st Sess. (October 22, 28 November 5, 10, 1981);
House Hearing, Clean Air Act Part 2, No. 97-103, 97th Cong., 1st Sess.
(November 19, 20, December 14, 16, 1981).
                                 -162-

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATON STUDY
                                            Section IV
    77See CAA § 306; CWA § 508; U.S. v. Sharon Steel Corp., 14 E.R.C.
1957,  1959  (W.D. Pa. 1980).

    7838 Fed. Reg. 25161 (September 12, 1973).

    79See 40 C.F.R. § 15.20(a)(3).

    80See 40 C.F.R. § 15.20 et seq.; Appendix A; discussed in U.S. v.
Sharon Steel Corp., supra note 77, at  1958-59.

    81See, e.g., Union Electric Co. v. EPA, 593 F.2d 299 (8th Cir.
1979); Fry Roofing Co. v. U.S. EPA, 554 F.2d 885 (8th Cir. 1977); West
Penn. Power v. Train, 522 F.2d 302 (3d Cir. 1975).

    82See, e.g., Conoco Inc. v. Gardebring, 503 F. Supp. 49 (N.D. 111.
1980), and cases cited in text.  See also Americ in Petroleum Institute
v. Costle, 17 E.R.C. 1334 (E.D. La. 1982).
         , e.g., Humana of South Carolina, Inc. v. Califano, 590 F.2d
1070, 1081 (D.C. Cir. 1978); Porter County Chapter of the Izaak Walton
League of America, Inc. v. Costle. 571 F.2d 359, 363 (7th Cir. 1981);
Rhodes v. United States, 574 F.2d 1179, 1181 (5th Cir. 1978);
Winterberger v. Teamsters, Local Union 162, 558 F.2d 923, 925  (9th
Cir. 1977).  The question of when judicial review of administrative
action may be sought also raises issues relating to the exhaustion of
administrative remedies and ripeness for review.  See, e.g. , Hooker
Chemical Company v. EPA, 15 E.R.C. 1721, 1724 (3rd Cir. 1981); Conoco,
Inc. v. Gardebring, supra; U.S. V. Sharon Steel Corp., supra ;  U.S.I.
Properties v. EPA, 16 E.R.C. 1408 (D. Puerto Rico 1981).
          Blessing v. United States, 447 F. Supp. 1160 (1978),  esp.
fns. 14, 18 and 26.

    85Id. at 1170.
                                 -163-

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Section V
                           V.  CONCLUSIONS


                                                            Page

A.    Introduction	   165

B.    Statement of Conclusions	   165

      1.  No New Indemnification Programs are Recommended
            at This Time	   165
      2.  Other Conclusions Concerning Indemnification
            on Equitable Grounds 	   170
      3.  Other Conclusions Concerning Indemnification
            Designed As An Incentive Or Disincentive • • •   175
                                -164-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section V
                             CONCLUSIONS

A.     Introduction

       This  section  focuses  on  the  principal  question posed by
Congress — under what circumstances,  if  any,  should indemnification
be accorded any  person as a result of  action taken by the Admin-
istrator?  Conclusions pertinent to  this  question  are stated, along
with a summary of the findings and reasoning supporting them.
Documentation appears in prior text.   We  have  not  made conclusions
with respect to  cost or financing  mechanisms because no new programs
were proposed for which cost or financing recommendations were needed.
However, cost and financing have been  considered both in general, and
in the evaluation of existing and  potential  programs.  Findings and
observations on  these points are included in the body of the report.

       The conclusions fall  into two  categories.  The first is a series
of findings supporting the  overall determination that no new indem-
nification programs are needed at  this time.   The  second category of
conclusions are  general ones that  are  more tentative and are perhaps
more correctly characterized as observations based on the overall
research and analysis involving the  issue of government indemnif-
ication.  They are  included to provide assistance  in the future con-
sideration of indemnification legislation.

B.     Statement  of Conclusions

       1.  No New Indemnification Programs are  Recommended at This Time

          This conclusion is based on  findings that (a) no justifica-
tion currently exists for expanding  existing EPA indemnification pro-
grams  into new areas of EPA jurisdication, (b)  an  analysis of likely
loss areas revealed no Justification for  recommending a new indem-
nification program, and (c)  there  is minimal current interest on the
part of the regulated industry in  such a  remedy.

          When evaluating the need for a  new indemnification program,
emphasis was given to the identification  of  current or past cir-
cumstances that  would be arguable  candidates for indemnification under
any of  the criteria identified in  prior analysis,  as well as to an
assessment of the probability that such circumstances may arise in the
future.  In general, few candidates were  identified.   While future
incidents could  not be ruled out,  the  probability  of such incidents
combined with past experience suggests that  these  incidents will be
infrequent, if they occur at all, and  that they probably will not be
similar if they  occur.  In  such a case little  would be gained by
establishing a new program  rather  than by addressing each Incident
individually.
                                 -165-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section V
           a.   There is no justification for expanding existing
               programs into new areas of EPA jurisdiction.

       Section 15 of FIFRA

       Evaluation of the need to extend § 15 indemnification to other
EPA  programs  indicated that TSCA would be the primary candidate for
possible  extension.  TSCA is the only other statute administered by
EPA  that  significantly regulates particular products, rather than pro-
cesses for wastes.   Application of  §  15 to TSCA would be unnecessary
because TSCA  incorporates many safeguards for inventory losses.  The
Administrator is given a large variety of regulatory options to reduce
risk under TSCA, but must choose the  least burdensome one for each
situation. Unlike  FIFRA, bans under  TSCA may not be made by admi-
nistrative order.   Instead, they oust either be by rulemaking or court
order,  thus allowing substantial opportunities for hearing.   The two
TSCA bans  implemented so far have been phased in and did not cover all
the  uses  of the  chemicals,  thus avoiding the problem of unusable or
unsaleable inventory.  Limited experience under TSCA prevents a final
conclusion, but  at  this time no FIFRA-like indemnification program
seems warranted.

       Section 202(a)(3)

       Based upon the current situation,  § 202(a)(3) indemnification
also should not  be  extended to other  EPA areas.  Both of the primary
candidate  areas  —the Clean Air Act and  RCRA — are fundamentally dif-
ferent  from the  Clean Water Act in  that  they do not involve  initial
government funding  of the cost of compliance.   The potential for
failure of innovative air pollution or solid waste technology does not
appear  to  be  a major disincentive to  the use of innovative technology.
Furthermore,  it  is  questionable whether  an incentive-type indem-
nification provision can function effectively without either the type
of funding provided by § 202(a)(2)  grants or a commitment to
demonstration project funding.   Because  construction grants  funding is
available  only for  municipal wastewater  treatment facilities, and
because private-sector water and air-pollution control demonstration
projects have been  significantly reduced by budget cutbacks, such an
extended indemnification program does not seem warranted.
Nevertheless,  if in the future significant encouragement of  the deve-
lopment of innovative technology is deemed to be appropriate, then
indemnification  comparable  to that  under § 202(a)(3) might be
considered.

      Section 113(b)

      Section 113(b)  of the Clean Air Act allows for an indemnity in
the  form of attorneys'  fees and other court costs when a court  deter-
mines  that EPA has  taken unreasonable enforcement action. This is
intended both to encourage  persons  (who  would otherwise not  do  so) to
                                 -166-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section V
 make  a  legitimate  defense,  as  well  as  to  deter unwarranted  EPA
 litigation.

      This  provision  does not  exist  in other  EPA statutes  and  is pro-
 bably not needed.   First, there  Is  no  indication from current  experi-
 ence under  the Clean  Air Act that such a  provision offers  a meaningful
 deterrent to unreasonable Agency action,  or that it is needed  to pro-
 vide an incentive  to  defend against  such  action.  Second,  with rare
 exceptions  there is no evidence  that judicial enforcement  undertaken
 by.EPA is "unreasonable" (although  such a term may be interpreted in
 various ways).  Finally, under current EPA enforcement policies and
 concurrence procedures, there  is little probability that unreasonable
 Judicial enforcement  will occur.  It should be noted that  the  Equal
 Access to Justice  Act already  ensures  for small businesses  much of the
 relief that might  be  provided  if §  113(b) were extended to  other EPA
 programs.

      Section 311(1)

      Section 311(1)  of the Clean Water Act allows  a nonliable oil
 spill discharger to recover voluntarily-Incurred cleanup costs.  The
 purpose is  to encourage fast, effective action by the person who is
 first likely to know  of the spill and  who may be able to prevent a
 more costly and damaging problem by  taking immediate containment and
 cleanup steps.  Section 311(1) has worked, but such a provision is
 probably not suitable for spills and similar  releases under other EPA
 statutes at the present time.  A somewhat different approach has been
 adopted by  the Comprehensive Environmental Response,  Compensation and
Liability Act of 1980 (CERCLA) that  applies to all  releases (other
 than oil spills).  Although experience  with CERCLA  is limited,  a need
 for further change Is not now indicated.

          b.  An analysis of likely  areas revealed  no justification
              for  recommending a new Indemnification program.

              The  categories of  losses  specifically evaluated  for
pot'ential indemnification were losses  due to:

              •   Agency release of  confidential business information;

              •   delays;

              •   conflicting requirements;

              •   emergency actions;

              •   unreasonable enforcement actions;

              •   change In Agency policy.
                                 -167-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section V
 An  evaluation  Indicates  little justification for a prospective indem-
 nification  program  under any of these categories.

       Confidential  Business Information

       No  EPA indemnification program seems warranted for losses
 resulting from unauthorized disclosure of confidential business infor-
 mation (C81).   Both negligent and  intentional unathorized disclosures
 are  arguably subject to  a suit for money damages under the Federal
 Tort  Claims Act.  The  extent of such disclosures appears to be quite
 limited,  and there  are both criminal sanctions against intentional
 disclosure  and elaborate security  provisions under FIFRA and TSCA
 which are designed  to  safeguard CBI.  Additionally,  congressionally-
 authorized  disclosures by the Agency are comparable  to other regula-
 tory  burdens that do not require compensation.
      An  indemnification program also  does  not seem warranted to deal
with  the  alleged problem of  losses  due to delays  in government permit
processing.  Both  industry and EPA  representatives  concerned  with the
problem of permit  delays have focused  on  remedial solutions other than
indemnification.   Furthermore, several studies have indicated that
regulatory problems are  not  often significant  causes of  delays in con-
struction of new power plants and other industrial  facilities.
Instead,  many delays  result  from such  problems as financing,  labor and
equipment availability,  and  management difficulties.

      Conflicting  Regulatory Requirements

      The theoretical problem of conflicting and  overlapping  regula-
tory  requirements  does not appear to be a problem warranting  an indem-
nification program.  While the type of interacting  requirements that
allegedly posed difficulty in the Tris case may well be  deemed to
justify indemnification,  no  similar Interactions  appeared  in  a review
of EPA programs.   At worst,  the  examples  found represent compliance
costs made necessary by  reason of other regulatory  standards.  This is
not normally regarded as a basis for indemnification,  but  rather an
ordinary  business  consequence of any regulatory program.

      Emergencies

      Although emergency action  seems  theoretically to provide
increased chances  for creating an indemnifiable loss,  the  Agency has
very  rarely used its emergency authority  to curtail private
operations.  The enactment of CERCLA has  provided EPA  with authority
for a coordinated  response to any emergency caused  by  release of
hazardous materials, according to the  National Contingency Plan.
Together  with Superfund,  which permits the government  Itself  to take
action in some cases, the new law replaces an  ad_  hoc response by court
                                 -168-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section V
Injunction with a  planned,  publicized  and  coordinated  approach.   This
reduces  the  possibility of  inequity,  to  the  point  that there  is  no
current  justification  for recommending an  indemnity program for  losses
caused by emergency action.

      Unreasonable Enforcement
      An expanded indemnity program  to  compensate  persons  subject  to
unreasonable administrative enforcement is  probably not  warranted.
This is primarily because there  is no evidence  that clearly unreason-
able enforcement exists on more  than a  very infrequent basis,  and
because EPA'a current enforcement policies  and  concurrence procedures
make such occurrences less likelycthan  ever before.  In  addition,  it
would seem preferable to accomplish  Agency  restraint through tradi-
tional avenues of judicial review, rather than  indirectly  by the
threat of indemnification.  The  former  route would encourage loss
anticipation and avoidance, while the latter route, if designed
effectively, could result in excessive  restraint and thus  interfere
with the Agency's enforcement mission.

      Changes in Policy

      Changes in policy may sometimes result in losses,  but the
changes are usually foreseeable  and  the losses  are usually within
expected risk parameters.  In addition,  policy  changes are usually  an
expression of congressional policy or the result of a rational and
defensible exercise of discretion delegated  to  the Agency  and are
rarely if ever due to Agency negligence or  misconduct.

          c.   Industry consultation  disclosed little Interest in
              indemnification as a means of  regulatory relief.

              Consultation with  representatives of the regulated
Industry indicated:

              o   Given the controlling statutory  provisions, most
                  persons felt that  EPA regulatory action  is usually
                  supportable.  They thought that  industry is given a
                  fair opportunity to participate  in rulemaking and to
                  avoid unnecessary  losses — especially in comparison
                  to other federal health and safety regulatory
                  agencies.

              o   Many felt that indemnification is not  an Important
                  issue and not politically  appropriate  in the current
                  legislative environment.

              o   Some expressed greater interest  in other regulatory
                  relief to solve particular problems and  did not feel
                  indemnification would  satisfactorily resolve the
                  problems experienced.
                                -169-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section V
               •   No persons interviewed described past losses of the
                   nature chat would obviously result in an indemnity
                   under  any of the theories and factors explored (with
                   the exception of losses related to programs already
                   in place).

               •   Interest  was expressed in keeping existing indem-
                   nification programs in place.

       2.   Other Conclusions Concerning Indemnification on Equitable
           Grounds

           a.   Whether Indemnification is warranted for an Inequity
               raises complex issues that are best considered In the
               context of the specific case and not resolved In advance
               by legislating a prospective indemnification program.

               (1)  Prospective Inequity indemnification programs are
                   not usually desirable unless based on a specific
                   event.

                   Certain indemnification objectives require that a
program be prospective in nature.   These objectives include
encouraging desirable private action,  such as voluntary oil spill
cleanup, or discouraging undesirable agency action, such as unreaso-
nable  enforcement  litigation.   However,  if the objective is to relieve
or correct some inequity, an indemnification program would not nor-
mally  be necessary until it  is clear that an inequity has occurred or
will occur.  When  based  on  a specific  event and the reasonable expec-
tation that there  will be repetitions  of that event,  a prospective
program may be  justified  to  avoid  the  costs and inefficiencies asso-
ciated with piecemeal  legislation.

                   Otherwise,  it is  difficult to justify such a program
in view of the potential  disadvantages.   These include:   (1) that the
program will encourage undesirable  behavior on the part of potential
recipients (e.g.,  less carefulness  to  avoid Indemnifiable losses);  (2)
that it will result  in undesirable  conduct on the part of the agency
(e.g., riskier conduct,  knowing that any adverse  impacts may be
compensated, or inappropriate  restraint,  in order to  avoid the costs
or inconveniences  involved);  (3) that  it will be  inaccurate In its
forecast of the costs  involved,  the  criteria that should be applied,
or the appropriate financing  mechanisms;  and (4)  that other signifi-
cant adverse Impacts may  have  been  ignored (e.g.,  interference with
other  agency missions).

                  Once legislation  is  in place, an agency must act
within its scope,  regardless  of  whether  it proves to  be Inappropriate
in some respect.   Congress,  on the  other hand,  may offer greater
assurance of its appropriateness by  waiting until events requiring
such legislation are clear.
                                 -170-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section V
               (2)  Specific  factors  supporting  or  oppossing indem-
                   nification  may  be  expected  to vary  from case to
                   case,   and  the  issues  raised are not readily
                   resolved  in advance  by the  design of a general rule*

                   Whether an  inequity  has occurred is almost always a
 function  of  circumstance  and  is highly dependent  on the character of
 the  injury,  its cause, who  was at fault  (if anyone),  whether the
 injury  could have  been foreseen or avoided, whether the loss could
 have  been mitigated,  and  other elements  typical of tort law analysis
 involving issues of  fault and remedy.  These  issues are rarely clear.
 In fact,  tort  cases  have  traditionally provided attorneys with excep-
 tional  opportunities  to practice  their skills  of  argument and per-
 suasion precisely  because each casecis unique  in  some respect.  Under
 tort  law, it would not be expected that  the answer would be simple or
 fit  precisely  within  a given  rule, and there  is little reason to
 expect  for the same  issues  to be  resolved more easily in the context
 of government  indemnification, if any  assessment  of the inequity is to
 occur at  all.

                   Aside from  the  inability to  determine the precise
 elements  of  an inequity in  advance of  a  specific  event, there are
 other significant  barriers  to the design of a  general rule.  Such a
 rule  requires  a commitment  to a specific future policy, reflecting not
 only  agreement that certain events amount to an inequity requiring
 redress,  but also  that compensation  (according to some rule of
 calculation) is the most  appropriate means of  redress.  Such a commit-
 ment would be  particularly  suspect given the traditional rejection of
 a compensation remedy by  Congress except in those narrow circumstances
 recognized under the Federal  Tort Claims Act and  the  Fifth Amendment.

                   In fact,  our research  Indicates in  every case to
 date but  one,  indemnification legislation has  been based on specific
 injuries; and  in almost every case the legislation has been excep-
 tional  in character and not indicative of a recurrent policy or series
 of similar events.  Moreover,  Congress usually prefers some other form
 of relief, such as an exemption or variance — or no  relief at all,
 thus creating  an incentive  among  those susceptible to injury to avoid
 it.  In such a climate it appears impractical  to  forecast the need for
 indemnification by resolving  highly  individual policy issues in the
 absence of specific circumstances in which these  Issues will arise.

                  The dilemma becomes  all the  more apparent if one
 attempts  the design of a  theoretical model to  use as  a guide for ine-
 quity indemnification legislation.  General criteria  pertaining to the
nature of the  loss, responsibility for the loss,  the  amount of
 compensation,  a financing scheme, and  administration  of the program
may be readily identified*  However, the relative importance of each
 factor may vary significantly depending  upon the  perceived importance
of indemnification as a policy objective in comparison to other objec-
                                 -171-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section V
 lives  from which indemnification may detract and depending on the
 availability of alternative loss avoidance and relief measures which
 may  obviate the need  for indemnification.

                   For example,  a difficult Indemnification administra-
 tive burden may currently be considered unjustifiable If It will
 require  the reallocatlon of agency resources away from a higher
 priority pollution control objective to administer the indemnification
 program.  In such a case, a variance may provide sufficient, although
 only partial relief.   However,  priorities may later shift so that the
 pollution control program involved is no longer rated more Important
 when the loss  occurs  to  a specific group, e.g., small fanners in an
 economically depressed area —  at least with respect to the realloca-
 tion of  program resources represented by administrative costs.  This
 problem  is compounded by the number of factors other than administra-
 tive costs which may  have an important role in determining the advisa-
 bility of an indemnification program, as well as the almost endless
 alternative loss avoidance and  relief mechanisms that might be made a
 part of  the rule;  and it Is rendered virtually unresolvable by the
 Infinite variations In policy preference which may arise due to unpre-
 dictable events.

           b.   Procedural protections may reduce the need for
               indemnification.

               Equity-based indemnification payments have been made in
 situations in  which full procedural due process had not been provided.
 While this is  not  the only factor supporting indemnification in those
 situations,  nor does  due process or proper procedure always work
 effectively to prevent a loss,  suspension or absence of procedural
 protections Is an  Important factor which can weigh in favor of
 granting  indemnity.

               The  participation of affected parties and the public In
 general  In regulatory proceedings provides notice of the agency's
 intentions,  and thus  a longer transition period within which to adjust
 to the regulatory  requirements.   It provides opportunities to
 challenge  the  assumptions or proposed solutions.  There is less likely
 to be an  outright  error  or an unfair devolution of the whole cost of a
 regulation on  one  group  after public discussion of an issue.

               Most  environmental statutes facilitate involvement of
 the  public  at  the  earliest possible stage of policy conceptualization.
This has  been  done  in response  to the need to avoid party actions or
unreasonable regulations.   There is much organized public involvement
 prior to  any rulemaking,  and the agency is frequently facilitating
 this involvement even when it is not specifically required to do so.
However, when  an emergency arises,  then the procedural protections
 such as  a  hearing  may be deferred until after the needed action is
 taken.   Usually,  though,  either  Congress or the agency recognizes the
                                 -172-

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Section V
potential danger and will undertake advanced  planning  to  anticipate
the way  in which such a matter  should  be handled when  it  arises.   The
growing  sophistication and sensitivity of  the administrative  process
to this  type of problem will probably  prevent,  in most  cases, blunders
like the DHEW announcement of the contaminated  cranberries.
Nevertheless, as in the past, indemnity payments are most  likely  to be
warranted and needed where the  process of  orderly regulation  has  bro-
ken down.

          c.  Indemnification for inequities  has not resulted in
              domino-like extensions of indemnification to other
              situations.

              An argument often raised against  the use  of  indem-
nification as a remedy is that  it will establish a legislative  prece-
dent that will be difficult to  avoid in the future.  Numerous requests
of a similar nature will arise  as a result, with predictable  adverse
impacts on budget and government administration at a minimum, and
possibly interference with other pressing  government objectives in
addition.

              Although it is not possible  to  state categorically  that
such concerns are illfounded, it seems unlikely that events justifying
indemnification would result in such a domino effect.   Two factors
would normally prevent it.  First, inequities are almost  always unique
in character.  What makes an event inequitable  may usually be
explained only by describing the entire event and its  unique  elements
of person, time, place, situation, intent  and misfortune.  The  appro-
priate remedy in such a case, whether  it is compensation  or some
alternative measure of relief, may also be attributed  to  considera-
tions that apply at that time to that  event —  the availability of
financing, the availability of  an appropriate administrative
mechanism, the political support or opposition, etc.   These unique
aspects of event and remedy should pose for future circumstances  only
the inconvenience of comparison, not the dilemma of inconsistency.

              A second factor involves the capability  of  Congress to
define indemnification objectives and  conditions in such  a way  that
the precedential effect is very limited.   It  is within the power  of
Congress to pass or reject indemnification legislation for almost any
reason, including strictly political reasons  (within constitutional
limitations); however, a clear  description of the factual  as  well as
political basis would forewarn  future  indemnification  constituencies
that arguments founded on legislative  precedents would  be  of  limited
persuasiveness.

              A review of proposed and enacted  indemnification
legislation points out that events for which  indemnification  has  been
proposed in the past are unique, that  the  congressionally  formulated
remedy has been different in most cases (not  always involving indem-
nification), and that no domino effect has occurred.
                                 -173-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section V
           d.   Some alleged inequities are not unique to EPA,  and
               solutions,  if warranted,  may need to be governraent~wide
               in scope.

               Certain alleged problems  which might merit consideration
 of  indemnification involve situations that are not unique to  EPA and
 may more  appropriately require consideration of broad statutory solu-
 tions  outside  the scope  of this study.   Such broad statutory  solutions
 might  Involve  either  an  Indemnification mechanism or they may involve
 broad  alternatives to indemnification.

               For example, certain losses might be dealt with by
 amendments to  the Federal Tort Claims Act which would reduce  some of
 the Act's  exceptions  to  the waiver of immunity.  Specifically,  the
 discretionary  function and misrepresentation exceptions might be
 modified  to permit tort  suits against the government where certain
 discretionary  functions  or misrepresentations are involved.
 Furthermore, some actions which might not now be covered under  the
 Federal Tort Claims Act  could specifically be authorized.  For
 example,  it is not clear  whether an action against the government for
 breach of  a trade secret  could be maintained under the Federal  Tort
 Claims Act.  If  considered necessary, an amendment to the Act could
 clarify the point.  But  limiting consideration and the effect of such
 changes to EPA probably would not be wise.   Piecemeal modification of
 the Federal Tort  Claims Act does not seem advisable.  If there  are
 possible  problems that are not unique to EPA,  then such problems
 should be  handled in  a government-wide  manner.

          e.   The private bill process  can continue to provide  relief
               of  last resort for inequities arising from EPA  action.

               Private bills have historically provided a process to
 redress inequities  that are not susceptible to a program or plan
 because they are  so unpredlctiable in nature or infrequent in
 occurrence.  The  existence of such a political process,  though  it is
 neither well known nor simple,  has sometimes provided a relief  valve
 for cases otherwise barred from the courts.  In the past when Congress
 has become aware  of a pattern of similar meritorious grievances pre-
 sented in private bills,  it has enacted general legislation to  deal
with the problem.  Thus,  the private-bill process can serve as  an
 interim remedial  mechanism until such time as a general relief  program
 proves warranted.

               The  special jurisdiction  procedure,  by which Congress
 removes a legal impediment to an otherwise  valid claim in the Court of
Claims, is particularly appealing for regulatory indemnification.
Congress can waive sovereign immunity or create a special exception  to
 some barrier to relief, tailored to the particular circumstance and
having no precedential value.   Then it  can leave to the court the
determination  of  liability in what is usually a complex factual situa-
                                 -174-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section V
 tion.   Further,  by  being  given jurisdiction,  the court  can pay any
 award  that  it  makes out  of  its own Judgment  Fund.   This technique is
 •faster,  and  results in sore  certainty of  payment than the
 •Congressional  Reference  procedure  in which the  Court  of Claims only
 advises  the  Congress, and  then sends its  recommendation back for final
 congressional  action.

               Nevertheless,  the private bill  process  can be lengthy,
 and  there are  no guarantees  that either Congress or the Court of
 Claims will  act  favorably, because the pitfalls of  the  political pro-
 cess are involved and because  all  private  bills request special
 exceptions.  It  should also  be noted that  private  legislation cannot
 provide  the  incentives to private  action or  the disincentives to
 government action that are the rationale for  some  kinds of Indemnifi-
 cation.  Since the  remedy is provided £d_ hoc, perhaps long after the
 loss and cannot  be  counted on  in advance,  It  will  not affect the
 behavior of  the  parties before the fact of loss.

      3.  Other  Conclusions Concerning Indemnification  Designed As An
          Incentive Or Disincentive

          a.  Indemnification  has  worked to provide Incentives to par-
               ties  outside the government.

              Several indemnification programs  demonstrate the bene-
 fits of using  indemnification  to encourage action  by  parties outside
 the federal  government.  These  include the diseased animal livestock
 program at the Department of Agriculture (to  encourage  destruction of
 diseased livestock  to prevent  spread  of the disease); the arts and
 artifacts indemnification program  (to facilitate museum display of
 foreign art  for  which losses would otherwise  be uninsurable);  the
 Superfund contractors indemnification clause  (to facilitate the remo-
 val and destruction of hazardous waste in  circumstances where liabi-
 lity insurance is inadequate);  the Clean Water  Act  innovative
 technology replacement grants  (to  encourage municipalities to try
 innovative waste treatment technology); and the Clean Water Act oil
 spill cleanup indemnification  provision (to encourage dischargers who
are not liable for  cleanup to  do so  voluntarily in  the  interest of
ensuring a rapid, effective initial  response).

              Two major advantages  in these indemnity provisions were
noted:   in some  instances they  ensure accomplishment  of public policy
objective that could not be undertaken by  the federal government
 (e.g.,  immediate, stop-gap cleanup measures); in others,  they offer a
more economical  option than federal  action because  of efficiencies
obtained in  private enterprise.  However,  these programs  are not
without potential disadvantages.   Notable  areas of  concern include:

      •   Agency supervision.   To  the extent  that the program
          establishes an obligation  to indemnify, design  measures must
                                 -175-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section V
           be  included  to ensure that  only those  actions consistent
           with  Agency  (or legislative)  priorities are actually
           indemnified.   Under the oil spill indemnity statute, for
           example,  unsupervised cleanup activity could result in the
           allocation of  funds to incidents or specific cleanup coste
           for a lower  priority category.   A mechanism employed under
           Superfund to  prevent this occurrence is to require that all
           expenses  be  preauthorized.

      •    Alternative mechanisms.  It Is  possible that the same con-
           duct  can  be encouraged by other mechanisms, or that natural
           Incentives already  exist which  make indemnification unnec-
           essary.   For  example, if specific losses are predictable,  it
           is  possible  that  a  procurement  proceeding, with concommitant
           advantages gained by planning and supervision, would prove
           more  economical or  more effective.  Under Superfund, tough
           sanction  provisions and narrow  defenses to liability are
           thought by some to  be more  significant cleanup motivation
           factors than  Indemnification.

      •    Congressional  and executive oversight.  Since incentive
           indemnification is  necessarily  prospective in nature, there t
           is a  greater  risk that the  mechanism,  as designed, will be
           off the mark  in some respect.  In the  diseased livestock
           program,  for example, it was  determined that federal
           inspectors, and not the indemnification program, controlled
           the spread of  disease;  and  indemnification was viewed pri-
           marily as subsidy.   This factor suggests the need for more
           careful monitoring  and review.

           b.  Indemnification for the purpose of restraining certain
              undesirable agency action is not clearly justified based
              on experience under existing EPA programs.  Moreover,
              the potential for adverse impact warrants very careful
              consideration before legislating an indemnification
              program for this purpo-se.

              The argument  that indemnification  may serve as an effec-
tive disincentive to undesirable Agency conduct  was raised under both
§ 15 of FIFRA and § 113(b)  of the Clean Air Act.  In the case of
FIFRA, it  was argued that the right to  indemnification might prevent
precipitous suspension actions by inducing the Agency to compare the
costs of compensation to  the  environmental risks involved in per-
mitting existing pesticide  inventories  to be used up.  In the case of
the CAA, it was argued that unreasonable  judicial enforcement action
might be prevented  by awarding attorney fees to  the opposing party
whenever a court determined the action  to be unreasonable.

              Under both  statutes,  experience indicates that the
indemnification provision has had minor if any impact as a disincen-
                                -176-

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Section V
 tive,  and  chat  other  factors  have been far more effective in accom-
 plishing  desired  restraint.   Under the CAA,  for example,  enforcement
 screening  procedures  for  all  judicial  actions  are  so  thorough
 (involving numerous layers  of EPA and  Department of Justice review),
 that  there have been  very few complaints  relating  to  error or
 harrassment.  Under FIFRA there  is a greater likelihood that the
 question  of indemnification may  have been persuasive  within the Agency
 as  a  negative factor  when considering  an  emergency ban.  However, in
 the relatively  few cases  in which suspension proceedings  have ensued,
 the Agency has  indicated  that either such bans were  imposed or the
 scientific evidence supporting a ban was  insufficient.   Further, it is
 widely  felt that  the  burden and  complexity of  procedural  requirements
 under § 6  have  served as  a  primary disincentive to the  Agency's
 reliance on suspensions,  thus preventing  the indemnification issue
 from arising at all except on a  very infrequent basis.

              As  an effective disincentive,  however,  the  indemnifica-
 tion provisions may be deficient for a more  significant reason.
 Currently,  neither provision  has actually posed the  threat of a signi-
 ficant  adverse  impact on  the  Agency.   Administration  has  proven to be
 feasible without  significant  costs, and the  Agency budget has not been
 responsible for the actual payout  of awards.

              In  either case,  it would be theoretically possible to
 make the disincentives more relistic — for  example,  by taking award
 payments out of the operating budget of the  office involved (without
 access  to  a supplemental  appropriation, as one version  of the Equal
 Access  to  Justice Act would have required),  or by  forcing the offi-
 cials involved  to undertake such burdensome  administrative require-
 ments that  their  primary  mission would necessarily be interrupted.
 Such an approach  would be exceedingly  difficult to justify in most
 circumstances,  however, unless the  underlying  regulatory  mission were
 insignificant in  comparison to the  policy favoring indemnification.
 Two risks  are raised:  that the  disincentive will  not work, in which
 case the indemnification  remedy  would  exact  its toll  on the Agency
 mission (as intended); and that  the disincentive will work too well,
 in -which case the Agency  may  be  deterred  from  taking  any  action at
 all.

              If  restraints on Agency  action are deemed necessary, it
would appear more logical to  address this  need directly by imposing
 procedural  hurdles, expedited review,  or  new statutory  criteria for
 the action  rather than indirectly  by establishing  economic
disincentives,  which may  have unpredictable  and costly  results.
                                 -177-

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Appendix A
                             APPENDIX A

                    BACKGROUND ON INDEMNIFICATION


                                                                 Page

I.    General Compensation Provisions 	  A-2

      A.  Introduction	A-2
      B.  The Federal Tort Claims Act	A-2

          1.  Background	A-2
          2.  FTCA Program Administration	  A-3
          3.  Important Exceptions to the FTCA	A-4

      C.  Fifth Amendment Taking	A-7

II.   Congressional References and Other Private Bills	A-12

      A.  Private Bills	A-12
      B.  The Court of Claims	A-1A
      C.  Congressional Reference Cases 	  A-15
      D.  Special Jurlsdication 	  A-17

III.  Non-EPA Instances of Indemnification	A-18

      A.  Agricultural Indemnities — Subsidies and Incentives.  A-18

          1.  Animal Disease	A-18
          2.  Dairy and Beekeepers	A-19
          3.  The Cranberry Scare of 1959	A-20

      B.  Indemnity Awarded for Government Error	A-20

          1.  Mlzokaml Spinach	A-20
          2.  Marlin Toy Co	A-21

      C.  Indemnification Being Considered for Policy Change. .  A-22

          1.  Tris Ban	A-22
          2.  Cyclamate Ban	A-23

      D.  Swine Flu Vaccine Program —
            Specific Incentive Situation	A-23

      E.  Indemnity in the Form of Ongoing Insurance Program. .  A-25

          1.  Arts and Artifacts. .	«	A-25
          2.  Defense Contracts 	  A-26
          3.  Non-Defense Contractors 	  A-26

Footnotes	A-28


                                 A-l

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Appendix A
                 I.  GENERAL COMPENSATION PROVISIONS
A.  Introduction

    The concept of sovereign immunity, which bars a  suit  against  the
government except with its permission, provides a key  to  understanding
the question of indemnification by the government.   Although  the  doc-
trine protects the government from being legally forced to  provide
compensation to injured parties, there are circumstances  where, by
either constitutional provision or statute, the government  has allowed
itself to be sued for money damages.  Specifically,  the Fifth Amend-
ment requires compensation when private property is  taken for public
use; and contract claims and some tort suits against the  government
have been authorized by statute.

    Judicial actions for damages, however, are narrowly prescribed,
and compensation is not generally provided in circumstances not
involving a taking of property, a contract claim, an action under by
the Federal Tort Claims Act, or some other specific  waiver  of immu-
nity.  Of course, there have been exceptions to the  general tendency
against indemnification, but these have involved unique circumstances,
and the judgment to grant indemnification has been made on  a  discre-
tionary basis.

    The traditional limitations on indemnification for the  adverse
effects of governmental actions partly involve a belief that  situa-
tions that might require indemnification should be avoided  so as  to
make such payments unnecessary.  If a loss cannot be avoided, then
payment of an indemnity is generally viewed as Inappropriate.  A  large
part of the attitude stems from a fear of creating precedents which
would require the government to make indemnity payments for a wide
range of regulatory activity.  This position has been  articulated and
exemplified by numerous authorities, Including fifth amendment taking
decisions, hearings on congressional reference bills,  court of claims
opinions in congressional reference cases, and Federal Tort Claims Act
decisions.

B.  The Federal Tort Claims Act

    1.  Background

        Over a century ago, the United States began  selectively
waiving its immunity from suit by enacting various laws allowing  con-
tract claims, patent infringement claims, claims arising  out  of the
activities of government-operated railroads and utilities,  and admi-
ralty and maritime tort claims against the federal government.  How-
ever, until the passage of the Federal Tort Claims Act (FTCA) in  1946,
if a person suffered personal Injury, property damage, or other finan-
                                 A-2

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix A
'Ci.a'1  loss  due  to  the  negligence of a federal employee acting on behalf
of  the  federal  government,  no court action was available for the
asse-ssment of  damages.^

         Thus before 1946,  a person who sustained injury from the tort-
ious  actions of the federal government was required to seek compensa-
tion  from  Congress.   Unless the claim fell within one of the limited
categories for  which  Congress had statutorily waived immunity (e.g.,
admiralty  and maritime  tort claims), it was necessary for the claimant
to  convince Congress  to  pass a private act covering the specific claim
and appropriating funds  for the payment of damages.

         As early  as 1832,  John Quincy Adams complained that Congress
was spending half of  its time considering private business, and
expressed  concern that  the  system was inefficient and inconsistent.
Partially  in response to this concern, Congress began, in the
mid-1800s,  to waive Immunity for certain specified claims and to allow
courts  to  take  over some of the burden.  By the 1940's, Increased
efforts  were made to  find  a way to relieve Congress of its burden of
private  legislation and  to  find a more equitable way to adjust the
growing  number  of tort  claims arising out of expanding federal
activity.   The  solution  adopted was passage of the FTCA in 1946, which
provided that the federal  government, with certain significant excep-
tions, could be sued  for the torts of federal employees acting within
the scope  of their employment.^

    2.   FTCA Program  Administration

         Any individual,  corporation, or other legal entity, with the
capability to sue as  such,  is eligible to file a claim or pursue a
lawsuit  under the FTCA.  There  are several prerequisites for a
claim:

         • A personal Injury,  property loss or death must have been
            suffered;

         •  The injury must have been caused by the negligent or
            wrongful  act or omission of a federal employee acting
            within the scope of his employment;

         •  The conduct  causing injury must be a tort under law of the
            state where  the conduct occurred;  and

         •  The conduct  causing injury oust not be within any of the
            FTCA  exceptions.

        Before  filing a  lawsuit,  claimants must present their claims
to  the appropriate agency for administrative adjustment.  Agency heads
have the authority to compromise or settle such claims.   If a claim
is  denied,  or if  the  agency head takes no action on the claim for six
                                 A-3

-------
     1980
                                 Total
                                                                               EXHIBIT 1
                                                                  CLAIMS AGAINST TUB GOVERNMENT UNDER
                                                                      THK FEDERAL TORT CLAIMS ACT
                                                 Asbestos
                                                                Aviation
                                                                                  Swine Flu
                                                                                                 Radiation       Admiralty    General  Torts    Mlacellaneous
I
(U
     Total Number
     of Claims

     Total Amount
     at Issue

     Judgments Against
     the Government (I.e..
     total amount awarded)
     1981
      2370



 $7,931.523.925

    $95.681,489
                                                    35
                                                                  204
                                                                                   122
$50.725,000  $1,007.206.900    $348.968.775

   $175,000     $25,298,176      $3,867,438
                                                                                                     11
                                                                                                                     23S
                                                                                                                                    1481
                                                                                                                                                      282
$65.000,000     $66.657,396   $3.409,160,495   $2,983.805,359

     0           $9,375.215      $49,899,962       $7,0b5,t>98
     Total Number
     of claims

     Total Amount
     at Issue

     Judgments Against
     the Government (I.e.,
     total amount awarded)
      1819



$13,484.447,265

    $74.999.783
                                                                  171
                                                                                   122
                                                                                                                     212
$34,500,000    $522,133,307    $277.274.645      $34.750.000

      0         $13.508.536     $10,407,423           0
                                                                                                                                    1124
                                                                                                                                                      177
                $67,179.290   $7.462,878,102   $5,085,731,921

                 $3,263.809      $42,425.471       $4,894,544

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Appendix A
months, a  lawsuit  may  be  filed.   Suits  under  the  FTCA are  tried  in  the
United States  district  courts  by  judges sitting without  juries.

    3.  Important  Exceptions to the FTCA

        From the perspective of this  indemnification study,  the  impor-
tant general exceptions to  the waiver of Immunity are those  involving
discretionary  functions and misrepresentation.' The exception  covering
interference with  contract  rights also  is  relevant.^  These  exceptions
effectively shield most governmental  regulatory activity from  tort
suits, although there are a few cases where this  shield  has  been
pierced to a very  limited extent.  In particular,  some courts  have
allowed personal injury suits  against the  government for negligently
conducting a government safety Inspection, such as a mine  safety
Inspection.

        a.  Discretionary Function Exception

            The discretionary  function  exception  of the  FTCA excludes,
from the waiver of immunity claims based upon  "the exercise  or per-
formance or the failure to exercise or  perform a  discretionary func-
tion or duty.  . .  . "^   The exception  applies both to negligent conduct
and wrongful acts  involving an abuse  of discretion.                  '

            While  the courts have not established an absolute  defini-
tion of discretionary functions,  their  opinions have focused on  the
nature and quality of the discretion  involved  in  the activities  that
are the subject of the  complaint.  The  key determinant seems to  be
whether a policy judgment or the  formulation of policy related to the
public interest is involved.   One court has noted several  considera-
tions or determinations that are  usually involved in policy-oriented
discretionary  decisions which  are immune from  suit:

            •    The evaluation of the  feasibility or practicability
                 of government programs;

            •    The balancing of cost  and benefit factors in  govern-
                 ment programs;

            •    The establishment of priorities  due to  limitations of
                 available resources;

            •    The balancing of competing policy considerations in
                 determining the  public interest;  and

            •    The promulgation of  new policies through  regulation."

            In recent years, courts have focused  on a distinction
between policy Judgments and operational activities in order to  inter-
pret and apply the discretionary  function  exception.'7  Where the
                                 A-4

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix  A
 courts  have  found  culpability  in  the  execution  of  operational  tasks
 (such  as  maintenance  of  a  road, a rescue  operation at  sea,  auditing  a
 federal credit  union,  use  of an aucomobile,  and  handling  hazardous
 materials  such  as  explosives), they have  generally found  the  govern-
 ment liable  under  the  FTCA.  On the other hand,  where  th->y  have  dis-
 covered culpability in the nature of  the  undertaking itself or in
 decisions  at  the policy  or planning level,  the  courts  have  usually
 held that  the exception  applies.   For  example,  agency  decisions  to
 issue regulations, seize and detain property, prosecute,  preserve
 wildlife,  accept bids  and  contract renewals, and run supersonic
 flights have  all been  considered  policy or  planning matters,  covered
 by  the exception and  immune from  liability.

            Generally, when the government  decides to  establish  and
 operate a  particular  program,  that policy decision Is  an  exercise of
 discretion at the  planning or  policy  formulation level, and exempt
 from the waiver of immunity under the  FTCA.  However,  once  the discre-
 tion is exercised  and  the decision made,  government employees  have no
 discretion to operate  the program negligently.^

            The setting of standards and  the application  of those
 standards  through  the  establishment of regulations clearly  Involve
 discretionary policy  judgments.   On the other hand, application  of the
 regulation to particular parties  and specific compliance, inspection,
 and enforcement activities might, under certain  circumstances, be
 regarded as operational rather than discretionary.  In particular,
 limited functions  of  lower level  officials, which  are  required by
 rules and  regulations  and which clearly specify  when official  action
 is  required,  fall  within the operational  category  and  are not  covered
 by  the exception.  Of  course, a determination of whether  the govern-
 ment official has  discretionary authority requires  a careful case-by-
 case evaluation of the particular statute or regulation involved.  The
 courts also seem to consider whether or not the  statute,  regulation,
 or nature  of  the activity allows  the claimant to rely  upon  the govern-
ment activity's being  handled properly.9

            Many claims under the FTCA have been for damages alleged
 to have been caused by the negligent issuance or wrongful failure to
 issue a permit, license, contract, certificate,  or  other  government
clearance  or authorization.  In the great majority of  cases, courts
have held  that the decision whether or not  to issue such  government
authorization involves the consideration  of a multitude of  factors,
some of which may be political and non-Justiciable, thereby rendering
 the activity discretionary within the meaning of the FTCA exception.*0

            In governmental inspection programs, the shield of the
discretionary function immunity may be breaking down.  During  the last
decade, a  number of personal injury claimants have  been successful in
cases based upon negligent government inspections  where the courts
have found the inspection to be an operational function involving pro-
fessional  expertise but little discretion.^
                                 A-5

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix A
             Consistent with the policy/operational distinction,  EPA
 decisions  to establish an Agency program,  regulate a particular  activ-
 ity,  issue  policy guidelines or locate a facility would be discretion-
 ary  planning or  policy decisions protected by the statutory exception.
 Generally,  licensing,  permit and certification activities are  simi-
 larly  protected.   However,  a negligent action or omission by EPA per-
 sonnel in  implementing the  programs could  be the basis of a suit under
 the  FTCA.

         b.   Hisprepresentation Exception

             As with the discretionary function exception, the  misrep-
 resentation exception  to the FTCA waiver of immunity relates to  the
 subject  matter jurisdiction of the court.   The misrepresentation
 exception prohibits "any claim arising out of ...  misrepresentation
 .  .  .,"  and the exception applies both to  negligent  and intentional
 misrepresentation.12   in construing this provision,  the courts have
 ruled  that  "misrepresentation" will be considered according to the
 traditional and commonly-held legal definition of the tort as  inter-
 preted under federal,  rather than state, laws.13  As decided by  the
 federal  courts, misrepresentation includes the failure to provide
 information as well as providing information that is wrong.

             The misrepresentation exception can cover actions
 involving personal  injury,  wrongful death, property  damage,  or finan-
 cial or  commercial  loss.  Most cases considering the applicability  of
 the misrepresentation  exception also involve the discretionary func-
 tion exception.   Generally,  the courts been more likely to deny  claims
 for commercial losses  than  claims involving bodily injury on the basis
 of the misrepresentation exception.15

             In cases where  faulty flight information from air  traffic
 controllers  has caused an accident,  the controller's advice  has  been
 regarded as  an operational  task negligently performed,  and the misrep-
 resentation  exception  has been held inapplicable.1°   On the  other
hand, one area in which the  misrepresentation exception has  consis-
 tently been  held  to apply is  in claims by  disappointed bidders for  the
construction  or repair of government property.1'

            A central  issue  in many misrepresentation cases  is the
actual source of  the claimant's harm.   The courts have held  repeatedly
that there  is a distinction  between negligent misrepresentation  and
negligent conduct,  with recovery as a result of the  former being
barred by the misrepresentation exception  to the FTCA.1**  in the regu-
latory context, there  have been a number of misrepresentation  cases
involving inspections,  certifications, and permits where the misrepre-
sentation exception has shielded the government from suit.19
                                 A-6

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Appendix  A
               governmental  body.   Only  the  second  and  third
               situations  are  thought  of  as  takings today.22

    The  Supreme  Court  recently  explained the  reason for  a  restrictive
approach to  compensation  for  regulatory  constraints:

               Suffice  it  to say that  government  regulation—
               by definition—involves the adjustment of
               rights for  the  public good.  Often this  adjust-
               ment  curtails some potential  for the use or
               economic  exploitation of private property.   To
               require  compensation in all such circumstances
               would effectively compel the  government  to
               regulate  by purchase.   "Government hardly
               could go  on if  to some  extent values incident
               to property could not be diminished  without
               paying for  every  such change  in the  general
               law."23

    The  Takings  Clause  of the Fifth Amendment traces its origins  to
the law  of England, but it  also reflects both the  colonial experience
and dominant legal  thinking of  that time.2*  Flowing first from  the
Magna Carta, basic  rights regarding property  were  brought  to America
by the English colonists.   In the  eighteenth  century,  eminent  domain
also became  recognized  and  accepted in the  American colonies as  an
inherent  and necessary  power of government.   At  the same time, private
parties  were afforded compensation for the  loss  of their property to
public use.

    During the nation's first century, the  taking  issue was rarely
raised.   When  the issue did arise, the concept of  a compensable  taking
was limited  by the  courts to an actual seizure of  land by  the  govern-
ment.  The Supreme  Court's  first major treatment of eminent domain and
the police power came in  1887.25   jhe claimant there was a brewer
whose business was  rendered worthless when  Kansas  enacted  a prohibi-
tion statute.  The  Supreme  Court concluded  that  the statute was  a
valid exercise of police  power, which involved no  direct Invasion of
claimant's property.  While the statute  impaired the use of the  pro-
perty, there was no taking  found because the  government had the  power
to regulate  property in order to abate a nuisance.26   With increasing
population,  rapid economic  growth, and urbanization in the late  nine-
teenth and early twentieth  centuries, the courts continued to  uphold
regulations  preventing nuisances to the  community  as a valid exercise
of police power and not a taking.

    In 1922, the Supreme  Court  reversed  its earlier line of cases and
stated that  the constitutional  question  with  respect to  taking turned
primarily upon the  degree of economic harm  Imposed by  the  government
regulation.27  in the few cases since then, the  Supreme Court  has
refused  to adopt any binding rule  for determining  where regulation
                                 A-8

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix A
 ends and  a compensable taking begins.28  This ambiguity has permitted
 the courts to  judge  each  case on its own merits.   However,  it has left
 no satisfactory  rationale from which to define the distinction between
 police  power and taking.

     The current  approach  of  case-by-case determinations of  whether a
 taking  has occurred  began in 1922,  when the Supreme Court dealt with a
 statute that forbade the  mining of  coal in such a way that  would
 affect  the structural soundness of  any house.29  The effect of the
 statute was to deny  to the owner of mineral rights to a particular
 property  the right to mine for coal.  Since the value of coal can only
 be  obtained if it is mined,  the mineral rights became worthless*  The
 court held that  the  statute  was an  unconstitutional exercise of the
 state's police power,  with the diminution in value of the property
 being the  key determinant that the  statute amounted to a taking.  It
 was the recognition  that  when the diminution "reaches a certain magni-
 tude, In most if not in all  cases there must be an exercise of eminent
 domain  and compensation to sustain  the act."30  The decision thus set
 out the mode of  analysis  that the constitutional  question of a taking
 depended upon the degree  of  injury  imposed by the regulation.  To a
 certain extent the court  also relied upon balancing the public gain
 against the private  loss,  although  the term "balancing of interests"
 was not stated.3*

     Thus,  an unconstitutional taking can be implied from a  substantial
 and burdensome interference  by the  government with a private property
 owner's use of the property.   To constitute such  an implied or de_
 facto taking, government  interference  with private property rights
 must be so substantial  as  to  deprive the owner of all or virtually all
 of  his  or  her interest  in  the property.   As a result, there is no
 taking  in  the constitutional  sense,  unless the interference is so
 substantial as to render  the  property  worthless or useless.

     In  a 1958 Supreme  Court  case, owners of gold  mines, closed in 1942
 by  direction of  the  War Production  Board (WPB), unsuccessfully sued
 the  federal government  to  recover damages for an  alleged taking of
 property.32 xhe Court  stated:

              [T]he  mere  fact that  the regulation deprives
              the property owner of  the  most profitable use
              of his  property is not necessarily  enough to
              establish the  owner's  right to compensation.33

 Since the  mine closures did  not  amount to a disposal of the owners'
 property or transfer  of their workers,  the Court  concluded  that the
UPB order  did not constitute  a taking.

    In  a 1979 decision, plaintiffs  were  charged with violations of
 federal statutes prohibiting  commercial  transactions in protected
 birds.3^   The Supreme  Court  explained  that a reduction in the value of
                                 A-9

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix A
 property was not necessarily equated with a taking, even though the
 most profitable use of the property was lost.  In this case the speci-
 fic regulation did  not compel a surrender or physical invasion or
 restraint upon the  bird artifacts.  Nor was all economic benefit
 denied to the owners.   The Court concluded that the cost of regulation
 is  a burden borne to secure "the advantage of living and doing busi-
 ness in a civilized community."-"  Similarly, in a 1980 taking case,
 the Court upheld a  rezoning of land overlooking San Francisco Bay,
 because the ordinance  in question only limited the number of residen-
 tial units that could  be built on the property and did not extinguish
 a fundamental right of property.36

     It is unlikely  that EPA programs will result in a Judicial finding
 of  a constitutional taking.  As a practical matter, the taking issue
 is  most likely to be raised in the regulatory context where EPA may be
 exercising its powers  to control air pollution, toxic chemicals, or
 the use of confidential business information submitted to the Agency.
 In  regulatory cases, the courts seem to employ a sliding scale,
 balancing the public health or interest against the individual's pro-
 perty right.   The regulatee must demonstrate a near total destruction
 of  the usefulness and  value of this property right.

     In one EPA case, a number of environmental groups, state govern-
 ments and utility companies sought review of regulations promulgated
 under the Clean Air Act to prevent significant deterioration of air
 quality in areas that  have air cleaner than the National Ambient Air
 Quality Standards.^7  Responding to plaintiffs' constitutional chal-
 lenge,  the D.C.  Circuit ruled that regulation of air pollution is
 within the federal  government's Commerce Clause powers.   Concluding
 that  these regulations could not be an unconstitutional  taking, the
 court explained  that,  while the use of private land was  limited, such
 a limitation  was not so extreme as to represent an appropriation of
 the  land.

    The  First  Circuit  similarly upheld an EPA transportation control
 plan  that  mandated  a 40% reduction in available off-street parking
 spaces.38   in  refusing petitioners'  constitutional arguments,  the
 court  focused  on the fact that this was a regulation of  uses,  that no
 title  was  taken,  and that other uses remained available.

    Recently,  the 1978 FIFRA amendments relating to agency use of test
 data  submitted by one  applicant to support a subsequent  pesticide
 registration  application by another applicant has been the subject of
 constitutional challenge.   Thus far,  the courts have concluded either
 that  plaintiffs  in  these cases do  not have a property right in the
data  or  that  the statute does not  effect a taking.

    A  number of  taking cases in the environmental field  have been
deemed  to  be  premature.   For example,  a pre-enforcement  constitutional
challenge  to  the Surface Mining Control and Reclamation  Act was held
                                 A-10

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Appendix A
not to be ripe because "mere enactment" of  the  statute  did  not  con-
sititute a taking.4°
                                 A-ll

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix A
         II.  CONGRESSIONAL REFERENCES  AND  OTHER  PRIVATE  BILLS
    Congress has historically used  private  legislation to  provide
relief  to  those who have suffered a loss  at  the  hands  of  the  govern-
ment and have no other means of  recovery.  Precisely because  they  are
available  when exceptions to the Federal  Tort  Claims Act  and  other
limitations apply, private bills have  constituted  a  safety valve for
exceptional cases.

    There  are three types of private legislation presently used by
Congress.  All can be used as relief from the  strictures  of sovereign
immunity in exceptional circumstances.  The  largest  category  consists
of private bills handled entirely within  the legislative  process and
funded  by  special appropriations.   Congress  enlists  the assistance of
the Court  of Claims for the two  other  categories of  private bills,
however.   Congressional reference cases are  those  private  bills
referred to the commissioners of the court of  claims for  hearings,
findings,  and a recommendation to Congress.  The cases are later
transferred back to the legislative body  for final decision,  and for
special appropriations if a claim is awarded.  Bills of special juris-
diction provide relief indirectly In the  form  of lifting  a Jurisdic-
tional  barrier.  A special jurisdication  is  conferred  on  the  Court of
Claims  for that case only, but it is final.  Judgment,  if  any, is  paid
out of  the court's Judgment Fund.

A.  Private Bills

    Private bills are produced by a legislative  process and passed by
a legislative body, but they do not have  the general applicability
that is usually characteristic of legislation  and  fundamental in
guaranteeing equal protection.  They are  specific  to a particular  per-
son or  situation.  It can be difficult to draw a line  between public
and private legislation because some public  legislation (some tax
bills,  for example) Is so narrowly  drawn  as  to apply only  to  a very
few people, though the language seems  to  be  general.  Most private
bills have nothing to do with the costs of regulation,  concerning
instead things such as moving expenses for government  employees,
pensions,  and permission to immigrate.

    The Constitutional basis for private  legislation is found in
Article I, § 8.  Congress is empowered to "pay the debts  ... of  the
United States." This has been held  by  the Supreme  Court for nearly 100
years to include moral or honorary  debts  as  well as  legal  ones:

                   The term 'debts' includes those debts  or
              claims which rest upon a merely  equitable or
              honorary obligation,  and which would not be
              recoverable in a court of law  if existing
                                 A-12

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Appendix A
facts, or written evidence that the Administration has withdrawn its
opposition.  Also, as a practical matter, since there is not wide
interest in any bill, it would be difficult to muster the two-thirds
majority in both houses to override a veto.^9  There have, in fact,
been few vetos, most of them in cases in which the statute of limita-
tions had been waived for a tax case.^"  These are explained by a very
strong administrative interest in the finality of tax determinations.

    The number of private bills has declined for a number of reasons.
Many situations that once required private legislation may now be
remedied through the regular judical system.  The Federal Tort Claims
Act is a prime example of a permanent waiver of sovereign immunity for
cases that had previously been handled by private bills.  Other simi-
lar statutes provide causes of action to prisoners for injuries
suffered in prison, and to government employees for waivers of over-
payment of wages.51

B.  The Court of Claims

    The Court of Claims was established in 1855 to help Congress with
the large volume of private bills.**  The original court was an advi-
sory board, hearing claims and reporting its findings and opinions,
together with recommended legislation, to Congress.  It quickly became
evident that this would not provide the help needed.  President
Lincoln thought the problem Important enough to address In his first
State of the Union message:

              It is as much the duty of Government to render
              prompt justice against Itself, in favor of
              citizens, as it is to administer the same be-
              tween private individuals. . .  It was
              Intended by the organization of the Court of
              Claims mainly to remove this branch of busi-
              ness from the Halls of Congress; but while the
              court has proved to be an effective and
              valuable means of investigation, it in great
              degree fails to effect the object of Its
              creation, for want of power to make its
              judgments final.^3

Two years later, the Congress had acted on President Lincoln's sugges-
tion.  The decisions of the Court of Claims were made final judgments
with appeal to the Supreme Court.54  However, the independence of the
court continued to be hindered because it could not pay judgments
until after appropriations had been "estimated" by the Treasury.  This
provision was repealed in 1866.55  After several changes In the way
judgments of the court were funded, the present system was estab-
lished, giving the court maximum independence from Congress.5^  A
Judgment creditor need only submit a certified copy of the Judgment to
the General Accounting Office to be paid.  Congress replenishes the
                                 A-14

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix A
 judgment  fund  periodically  in  lump  sums.   This minimizes the possibil-
 ity  that  a  particular  claimant  will  be  denied payment by Congress
 after  award by  the  Court  of Claims.

    The jurisdication  of  the court  has  been expanded by a number of
 statutes.   The  best known Is the  Tucker Act,  which describes the
 general Jurisdiction of the court:

              The Court of  Claims shall have  jurisdiction to
              render judgment upon  any  claim  against the
              United States founded  either upon the Consti-
              tution,  or  any Act  of  Congress, or any regula-
              tion of  an  executive  department, or upon any
              express  or  implied  contract  with the United
              States,  or  for liquidated or unliquidated
              damages  in  cases  not  sounding in
              tort. .  . .57

    The Court of Claims now has jurisdication over most money claims
 against the  government, with the  prominant exceptions of tort and
 pension claims.^  In  all cases the  government is the defendent  and
 there  is no  jury trial.   In. the year ending September 30,  1981,  the
 Court  of Claims heard  772 petitions  involving 2,304 plaintiffs.59

 C.  Congressional Reference Cases

    The desirability of having  a  judical body render assistance  to
 Congress in  deciding private relief  bills  has long been evident,  but
 it was not  until 1966  that  a procedure  was perfected.  In 1962,  the
 Supreme Court found the Court of  Claims to be an Article III court
 (part  of the Judicial, rather than  the  Legislative Branch of govern-
 ment ).'^  Until then,  both  judges and commissioners"'- on the court  had
 participated in the resolution  of reference matters for Congress.
Although the Court did not  explicitly decide  the issue, both the
majority and concurring opinions  suggested that congressional refer-
ence jurisdiction was  incompatible with the judicial power of an
Article III court because it involved advisory opinions rather than
active controversies.^2   xhe Court  of Claims  thereupon largely ceased
 to accept new reference cases,  though it continued work on those
pending.^  Four years later, Congress  revised the congressional
reference statutes to  provide that only the trial commissioners,  not
the Article III judges, would take  reference  cases.  The standard of
 recovery in  the statute did not change:

              The trial commissioner .  . . shall proceed in
              accordance  with the applicable  rules to deter-
              mine the facts, including facts relating to
              delay or laches,  facts bearing  upon the ques-
              tion whether  the  bar of any  statute of limita-
              tions should  be removed,  or  facts claimed to
                                 A-15

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Appendix A
              excuse  the  claimant  for  not  having  resorted  to
              any  established  legal  remedy.   He shall  append
              to his  findings  of  fact  conclusions  sufficient
              to inform Congress whether the  demand  is a
              legal or equitable claim or  a gratuity,  and
              the  amount,  if any,  legally  or  equitably due
              to the  claimant.*>*

    The procedure  followed  for  the congressional  reference  cases  is
similar to that for other  private  bills,6^ except  that the  committee
passes a resolution to refer a  bill  to the court,  rather than  to  pay
compensation.  These  are  one house resolutions.   It  is not  until  the
case is transmitted back  to Congress from  the commissioners that  the
bill embodying the award  is passed by  both houses.   Congress has
followed the recommendation of  the commissioners  in  nearly  all of
about 100 reference cases  since World  War  II.66

    The reference  procedure is  very  little used now.   It has been a
year since the last case was referred  to the  court,  and only five
reference cases are under  consideration in the Senate.6'  This may be
due, in part, to the  unfamiliarity of  the  legal profession  with the
reference procedure,  and  to the fact that  congressional committees aye
more likely to decide the  cases themselves.

    Although there is still some debate about what is  meant by an
"equitable claim or a gratuity," the case  that seems to embody the
majority view is Burkhardt v. United States,  where the Court said that

              [T]he term  "equitable  claim" as used in  28
              U.S.C.  2509,  is  not  used in  a strict technical
              sense meaning a  claim  Involving consideration
              of principles of  right and justice  as  adminis-
              tered by courts  of equity, but  the  broader
              moral sense  based on equitable  considera-
              tions.68

Many congressional reference cases have since read Burkhardt's defini-
tion of equity Into the statute.   In spite of the  expansiveness of the
standard, it by no means  indicates that a  favorable  recommendation is
made in all congressional  reference  cases.6'

    Many recent congressional  reference decisions  have added a more
concrete standard  to  help  separate the equitable  claims from the
merely gratuitous —  that  the  plaintiff base  its  claim on  some unjus-
tified act or omission of  the  government.^   The  requirement of fault
is still a matter  of  controversy.
                                 A-16

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Appendix A
 D.   Special Jurisdication

     The  last category of private bills are  those  that confer  special
 Jurisdication on the Court of Claims for a  particular case.   These
 usually  remove some affirmative defense of  the government  such  as res
 judicata or an expired statute of limitations.  The judgment  of the
 court  is final in these cases, and they are not transmitted back to
 Congress for approval or appropriations.

     The  Supreme Court has held that directing the Court of Claims to
 decide a case on the merits after removal of a legal impediment does
 not  unconstitutionally interfere with the separation of powers.7^  The
 basis  of congressional authority is the power to determine and  pay
 debts.  In Sioux Nation, the Supreme Court  held that precedents
 "clearly establish that Congress may recognize its obligation to pay a
moral  debt not only by direct appropriation, but also by waiving an
 otherwise valid defense to a legal claim against the United
 States."72

    An example of a past special Jurisdication bill granting  indemni-
 fication is the Hizokami Brothers spinach case.  The private  law
directed the court to decide the case notwithstanding the  fact  that it
clearly fell within the misrepresentation exception of the Federal
Tort Claims Act.7^  The court awarded damages for the mistaken  deter-
mination that the spinach was contaminated  with a pesticide.

    In addition to waiving a defense, special jurisdiction bills some-
times direct the Court of Claims to take particular factors into con-
sideration in its decision.  Such instructions are consistent with the
rule that the sovereign may condition its consent to suit.7^  The bill
providing compensation for losses due to the ban of Trie-treated
children's sleepwear Is a current example of a special jurisdiction
bill containing criteria for decision.'5
                                 A-17

-------
                          US DA DISEASED  LIVESTD^^INDEMNIFICATION  PROGRAM




                               ESTIMATED OBLIGA^TONS FOR  INDEMNITIES




                                      (Dollars  In Thousands)

1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
TQ
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981

- Actual
- Actual
- Actual
- Actual
- Actual
- Actual
- Actual
- Actual
- Actual
- Actual
- Actual
- Actual
- Actual
Brucellosis
$ 1.245
1,184
3,175
4,163
4,771
8,354
12,821
2,271
10,784
14,768
14,666
18,963
26,548
Cholera
$3,748
2,064
788
3,129
46
	
479
912
2
	
—
	
	
Scrapie
$ 55
33
17
21
12
28
38
2
10
124
68
347
358
Tuberculosis
$ 153
456
678
977
627
1,072
1.446
167
1,579
1,761
329
2,102
1,293
Newcastle
$ "~~"~
	
6,410
24,393
507
41
55
1
854
	
823
740
416
Total
$ 5,201
3,738
11,068
32,683
5,963
9,495
14,839
3,353
13,229
16,653
15,886
22,152
28,615
       TOTALS
$123,713
$11,168    $1,113
$12,640
$34,240
$182,875
Source:  Division of Veterinary Services, Animal and Plant Health  Inspection  Service,  USDA.

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Appendix A
              III.  NON-EPA INSTANCES  OF  INDEMNIFICATION
A.  Agricultural Indemnities — Subsidies  and  Incentives

    More  indemnification programs are  connected  with  agriculture  than
any other single enterprise.  To a  certain extent,  this fact  reflects
a policy  favoring agricultural subsidies,  in keeping  with  the national
interest  in a healthy agriculture sector.   It  may also be  a reflection
of the  political power of farm interests.   There are  also  more speci-
fic and substantive reasons for the indemnity  programs, however.  One
is that the losses to which the agricultural indemnities respond  are
frequent  and predictable, both in the  sense that fanners are  certain
to suffer losses of these types and that there has  been sufficient
experience to estimate the size and frequency  of the  losses.   When
there are a large number of losses,  it  is  much more efficient to  set
up a program that can respond automatically rather  than treating  each
one separately.

    Pesticide problems are the basis for most  of the  agricultural
indemnity programs.  All except the animal disease  program address  the
problem of a farmer caught between  the  conflicting  goals of using
pesticides to increase productivity and protecting  the public food
supply  from contamination by dangerous  residues.  When food is barred
from the  market because of unacceptable pesticide residues, notwith-
standing  the farmer's lawful use of  them,  part of the loss has con-
sistently been shifted to the government.

    1.  Animal Disease

        The animal disease program  is  the  oldest statutory indemnity
program,76 and probably the most costly.   It accompanies and  supports
a cluster of programs aimed at the  erradication  of  particular live-
stock diseases.  The money paid for  destruction  of  diseased and
exposed animals acts as an incentive for farmers to cooperate.77  Over
the years the USDA has adjusted the  payments so  that  they  are high
enough  to induce support, but not so high  as to  make  diseased animals
a "good business."7°  There this is  still  an incentive for farmers  to
keep the  herds healthy.

        The program operates under  regulations written by  the
USDA,79 but Is jointly administered  with the states.  Animals are
Inspected by either state or federal offlcals  and,  if diseased, are
usually appraised at the same time.  Indemnification  payments are then
made quickly.  The amount varies, but  is usually less than the
replacement value of the animal.  Regulations  set a maximum dollar
amount  for each disease, with a wide variety of  factors to be consid-
ered.   For example, cattle exposed  to  tuberculosis  are eligible for up
to $450 per animal, but combined federal and state  payments,  plus
                                 A-18

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Appendix A
salvage,  If any, may  not  exceed  the appraised  value.  "  The  amounts  of
the awards may be challenged,  though  they  rarely are.81

        The program is  funded  by  regular appropriations.   Each  program
is separately considered  in  internal  budget development,  but none  is a
line item in the budget sent to Congress.  Therefore, up  to  ten per-
cent of appropriated  funds may be shifted  from one program to another
without congressional approval, if estimates prove incorrect.  If  the
Secretary of Agriculture  declares a national disease  emergency, funds
for erradication and  indemnification  may be borrowed  from the
Commodity Credit Corporation,  and later paid back by  appropriations.
Administrative costs  are  estimated at 10-12 percent of the amount  paid
out.82  As the table  on the  previous  page  shows, the  total amount  paid
out is substantial.
                                   c
    2.  Dairy and Beekeepers

        The dairy&3 and beekeeper*^ programs are not  designed to
induce behavior changes but  to compensate  for  pesticide-related
losses.  The beekeepers program compensated for the damage done to
bees by pesticides developed as substitutes for DDT.**5  Congress
apparently decided last summer that the beekeepers had had enough  time
to adjust to the change and  find ways to protect their bees. The
program was thus officially  terminated, after  OMB had cut its budget
for several years.  The dairy  program remains, but is much reduced
from its peak, when $350,000 a year was distributed to dairy farmers
who were prevented from marketing milk that had unacceptable pesticide
residues through no fault on their part.   Apparently, current pestici-
des are not as persistent, and do not prevent  milk from being marketed
as often, because only $40,000-50,000 a year is now being paid."

        One recent contamination incident  threatens to upset the
orderly operation of  the  dairy program.  Unacceptable amounts of hep-
tachlor appeared in milk  from  cows in Hawaii.  The source appears  to
be pineapple wastes.  Pineapple companies  have been given a  temporary
exemption to use heptachlor  to control mealy bugs.  It was thought
that mulching and aging the  skins and tops reduced the heptachlor  con-
tent sufficiently.  It is not  clear whether the process was  faulty or
whether the feed had  simply  not been aged  long enough.  The  immediate
problem is that there is  not nearly enough money in the indemnity
budget to cover the potential  claims of millions of dollars. The
Hawaii congressional delegation is investigating possbilities for  aid
to the dairy farmers.^

        Both programs were administered by state and  county  agri-
culture stabilization and conservation committees under regulations
promulgated by the USDA.88  The delegation of  authority only extended
to implementation, however,  and the local  committees  were not per-
mitted to make modifications or waivers.   Payments were made quickly,
from funds Included in the USDA's regular  appropriations.
                                 A-19

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix A
     3.   The  Cranberry Scare of 1959

         Early  in November of 1959,  then Secretary of  Health,  Educa-
 tion, and  Welfare Arthur Fleming,  held a news  conference to urge the
 public  not to  buy cranberries grown  in Washington or  Oregon.   It was
 feared  that  these cranberries were  contaminated  with  the herbicide
 aminotriazole  which had  been found  to  cause  cancer in rats.  The
 Secretary  could  not assure the public  that cranberries from other
 states  were  free of contamination.   As a result,  virtually the entire
 cranberry  crop remained  unsold at  the  end of the  year.  This  threat-
 ened ruin  for  the cranberry growers, as almost all of their sales are
 for Thanksgiving and Christmas.

         Apparently,  the  farmers  were able to mobilize a great deal of
 political  pressure and,  by the beginning of  February, 1960, the USDA
 had designated the cranberry producing states  as  areas in which the
 Farmer's Home  Loan Administration could make emergency loans.  During
 the next six months,  $333,000 was loaned to  30 growers.89  At the end
 of March,  the  White House announced  an indemnity  program to compensate
 the growers  of untainted cranberries who had been unable to sell their
 crops due  to the scare over the  contaminated ones. Under the program,
 the growers  of contaminated cranberries were ineligible to receive   »
 indemnification.   The USDA used  an established fund for the
 payments.^0

         This was the  first time  that the FDA had  used its power of
 national publicity to warn the public  of an  imminent  danger.   The
 reaction of  the  consumers was so immediate and overwhelming,  that just
 the threat of  similar publicity  has  since motivated many other com-
 panies  to  institute  voluntary recalls.^l

 B.  Indemnity  Awarded for Government Error

    1.   Mizokami  Spinach92

         During the summer of  1962, the  Mizokami Brothers shipped ten
 railroad cars  of  spinach east from Colorado.   The FDA conducted
 routine  paper  chromotography  tests to  check  for pesticide residues.
Eight of the carloads showed  no  residues in  excess of established
 tolerances,  but  tests on two  carloads  indicated unacceptable  residues
of heptachlor.   Shortly  after Mizokami  was notified,  the two  car loads
were seized.   The growers could  not understand what had produced the
contamination  because they had not used heptachlor.  Mizokami hired
 two chemists (one was the inventor of  heptachlor) to  do additional
tests and  to testify  for them.   Following a  hearing,  the FDA  sent
 samples  to Washington, for a  more sophisticated gas chromotography
 test.  The new tests  showed no trace of heptachlor, and in a  letter of
September 24,  1962 the FDA admitted  that the original paper chromo-
 tography test  must have  been  in  error.
                                 A-20

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix A
         In the  interim,  the  Mizokami  Brothers  had  plowed  under a good
 deal of their 1962  crop,  presumably because  spinach is  a  fragile com-
 modity that could not  be  stored  until the  debate  had concluded.   The
 rest of the 1962 crop  was sold at  reduced  prices.

         In 1964, a  private bill  conferred  special  jurisdiction upon
 the  Court  of Claims to hear  and  render judgment on the  claims of the
 Mizokami Brothers.93   Although the misrepresentation exception would
 have precluded  recovery under the  Federal  Tort Claims Act,  the court
 held that  the private  law had waived  sovereign immunity and conceded
 liability,  but  had  left leaving  causation  and  damages for the court to
 decide.

         The Mizokami Brothers were awarded $301,974.33  in 1969 from
 the  Court  of Claims Judgment Fund.  Most of  the award ($227,399) was
 for  the  spinach that was  plowed  under in 1962, and the  majority of  the
 rest for the reduced price sales in 1962 ($49,904).   The  court also
 awarded  attorney's  fees and  court  costs.

     2.   Marlin  Toy  Co.

         The only other case  in which  the Commissioners  of the Court of
 Claims  recommended  indemnification for an  agency error  was  to the
 Marlin Toy  Company.  Two  of Marlin's  toys  were included on  a holiday
 list of  banned  products for 1973,  one described as "without plastic
 pellets."9*  This was  an  error as  only the version with pellets  had
 been banned,  the other was approved.   Marlin was unable to  rectify  the
 mistake  in  time for Christmas sales.   Because  this was  clearly a
 misrepresentation,  Marlin had no cause of  action under  the  Federal
 Tort Claims Act, and instead went  to  Congress  for  relief.

         CPSC  supported the private  bills referring the  case to the
 Court of Claims under  the congressional reference  procedure.9^  On
 December 19,  1978,  the Review Panel advised Congress that Marlin had
 an equitable  claim  of $40.000 against the  government, payment of which
 would not be  a  gratuity.9"  A bill  awarding this amount to  Marlin was
 passed by the Senate during the  96th  Congress, but not  acted upon by
 the  House.  No  bill was reintroduced  during the current Congress.

        The Incident also  led Congress  to  add  § 5(h) to the Consumer
Product  Safety  Act.97  It  creates  special  exemptions that allow
 claims based  on misrepresentation  and deceit otherwise  barred by the
FTCA.  However, the claim may not  be  made  with respect  to any agency
 action,  as  defined  by  the  Administrative Procedure Act.  Although ori-
ginally applicable  only to claims  arising  before January  1, 1978, the
provisions  have since been indeflnately extended.  It is  not clear
 that  the Marlin Toy Company could  have been successful  in making a
claim under §5(h).  Although the lists of  banned hazardous  substances
are  the  result  of adjudication or  rulemaking,  they are  considered by
 the  Commission  to be official actions as they  are  published in the
Federal Register after a  vote by the  Commission.9**
                                 A-21

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix A
 C.   Indemnification Being Considered for Policy Change

     1.   Tris  Ban

         In 1971  and 1974 the Department of Commerce and its successor
 in  administering the Flammable Fabrics Act, the Consumer Product
 Safety  Commission (CPSC), promulgated flame-retardant performance
 standards  for children's sleepwear.^  Early in 1976, the Environ-
 mental  Defense Fund petitioned the CPSC to require labeling for Tris-
 treated garments,  based  on the results from salmonella mutagenicity
 tests.   On April 7, 1977, after analyzing two rodent feeding studies
 done  by the National Cancer Institute, the CPSC declared children's
 apparel containing Tris  to be banned hazardous substances.

         The impact of the Commission's action did not fnll evenly on
 the  industry.  On  the upper end of the manufacturing chain, the chemi-
 cal  production of  Tris had apparently ceased by the time of the ban so
 that  the chemical  companies had little inventory.*00  On the lower
 end,  the repurchase provision of the Federal Hazardous Substances Act
 worked  well.^i  The goods held by customers were repurchased by
 retail  stores, their merchandise was repurchased by distributors, and
 the distributors returned it to the manufacturers.  There the flow ^
 stopped.   The  American Apparel Manufacturers Association brought suit
 to compel  the  CPSC to extend the original ban from just garments to
 include all fabric treated with Tris.  Under court order, the Commis-
 sion  did so.   But  when it tried to enforce the repurchase provision by
 having  the fabric  mills  buy from the manufacturers, the mills chal-
 lenged  on  the  grounds that the procedure used to extend the ban to
 them  had lacked  required notice and comment opportunities.  Eventually
 the suits  were settled,  with the mills agreeing not to challenge the
 ban on  fabric  any  further,  if the CPSC would not enforce the repur-
 chase provisions against them. ^2  Suits brought to enforce private
 rights  of  repurchase also failed.  This left the manufacturers holding
 the entire inventory.  According to testimony in the Senate, the manu-
 facturers  are  a  group of about  100 companies, each having annual sales
 of under $10 million.  The total loss in inventory due to the ban is
 now estimated  at between $50.1  and $56 million.^

        A  public bill to reimburse businesses adversely affected by
 the Tris ban passed both Houses, but was vetoed by President Carter in
 1978.   A new legislative proposal would confer special jurisdiction on
 the Court  of Claims to hear and render judgment on claims for losses
 resulting  from the Tris  ban.104  it does not concede federal liabil-
 ity.  The  bill directs the court to consider many specific factors in
determining the  validity of the claims and the extent of losses.
Among them are:

        A)  Whether reasonable  alternatives to Tris existed at the
            time of the  flammabllity standard;
                                 A-22

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix A
         B)  Whether the claimant  could or should have tested Tris for
             chronic hazards;

         C)  The degree of good  faith of the claimant in complying with
             the flammability  standard, the ban,  and export provisions;
             and

         D)  The extent to which the  claimant relied in good faith on
             assurances from suppliers.

         Chemical manufacturers  of Tris may not make claims under this
 statute.   No compensation is  allowed for lost profits,  proceeds from
 distress sales, attorneys'  fees,  or  interest. Although special jur-
 sldiction bills often  give the  Court of Claims some direction,  the
 Tris  ban bill is unique in the  specificity of its  instructions.  Most
 of  the  factors are  aimed at sorting  out the equities of the compli-
 cated factual situation.

    2.   Cyclamate Ban

         Those holding  stocks  of cyclamate-sweetened goods  when  it was
 banned  in 1969 have been trying ever since to obtain Indemnification
 for their losses.   The House  passed  a bill in 1971  that would have
 given the Court of  Claims jurisdiction to  hear claims,  and specially
 appropriated an estimated $120 million for payment.10'   No bill passed
 the Senate. 1-06  Several years later  however,  the Senate passed  and
 conveyed  to  the Court  of Claims a congressional  reference  on the issue
 of  relief for the California  Canners and Growers Association.1^
 After years  of motions,  extended  discovery,  and  briefs,  the opinion of
 the trial commissioner is expected soon.

        The  arguments  revolve around the fact that  cyclamates had been
 on the  FDA's GRAS list  (Generally Recognized  As  Safe).   The Industry
 claims  that  it reasonably relied  on  that assessment of  the substance,
 and that  it  had insufficient  warning of an adverse  action.   The
 government argues that  the  listing implied no conclusive determina-
 tion, and that the  industry was well aware of the growing  concerns
 about the substance.108   ^8 U8ualt the equities  of  the  situation are
 not clear, and depend  upon  an examination  of  all of the  facts.

        Even if the  trial commissioner recommends an award,  Congress
will  have  to  pass a  special appropriation  to  fund it.   Thirteen years
have  passed  since the  loss.

D.  Swine Flu  Vaccine Program—Specific  Incentive Situation

    The possibility  that  liability problems would drive  vaclne  manu-
facturers out  of  the business had been a matter  of  concern at HEW for
some  time.   During  the  spring of  1976,  as  the  agency planned a  mass
 innoculation against swine  flu, it became  a more immediate  and  more
                                 A-23

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix A
 critical  issue.   Vaccinating tens of millions of people with a new
 vaccine has  an unquantified, but certain risk of serious side effects
 for some  of  them.   In  addition to this,  the insurance companies
 worried about  groundless  and ultimately  unsuccessful suits that they
 would  have  to  face.

     HEW's response  to  drug company concerns was proposal to assume the
 duty to warn through the  procurement contracts.  The insurance com-
 panies ultimately refused to provide liability coverage on this basis.
 Congress  discussed  indemnity legislation,  but failing to agree on a
 solution, asked manufacturers to resume  their negotiations.  Into that
 deadlock  dropped news  of  Legionnaires' Disease, which was suspected for
 four days of being  caused by swine flu.  New legislation was intro-
 ducted giving  victims  a right to sue the federal government on the
 model  of  the Federal Tort Claims Act,  instead of providing an indem-
 nity.   In less than two weeks the bill was passed by both Houses and
 signed by President Ford.^9

     In a  fairly complicated  arrangement, the government agreed to
 accept the vaccine manufacturers'  potential strict product liability
 for personal injuries  due to the vaccine.   Under this scheme,  an
 Injured victim is permitted  to sue only  the federal government under
 the law of his state.  If negligence is  proved, then the government
 can in turn  recover from  the parties responsible for the negligence.
 The bill  also  eliminated  the possbllity  that the manufacturers could
 earn a profit  on the swine flu vaccine sold to the government.

     Vaccines are a special case,  probably  not duplicated in situations
 under  EPA's  jurisdiction.  They are  important to public health,  highly
 regulated, and produced by only a few manufacturers because the  risks
 are so great.  In spite of the most  thorough adherence to government
 specifications and the greatest degree of  care, vacines can cause a
 certain number of severe  adverse  reactions in the vacinated popula-
 tion.   Swine flu is the only vaccine for which the federal government
has assumed  liability, however.110

    There is a national interest  in  having enough vaccine to prevent
an  epidemic  (even though  a swine  flu epidemic did not develop).
Indemnification was used  as  an incentive to induce the production of
swine  flu vaccine, rather than as  a  subsidy to the entire industry.
There  also is  an element  of  joint  responsibility in this situation,
since  vaccine making is heavily regulated,  and public health is  a tra-
ditional concern of the federal government.

    The Department of Justice  has  administered the entire swine  flu
compensation program, Including claims processing,  settlement  and
litigation.   The administrative costs are  paid out of the regular DOJ
budget, and  the awards are paid in the same manner as Federal  Tort
Claims Act awards.111
                                 A-24

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Appendix  A
     As  of  December  18,  1981,  over  4,000  claims  totaling  $2.95  billion
dollars had  been  filed.   Of  these,  2,773  (for $1.91  billion) have  been
denied, and  263 settled  administratively (for $6.24  million, rather
than the $115 million  claimed).  Some  1,500  suits  have been  filed; 845
of  them still pending,  341 dismissed,  234 settled  (for $22 million
rather  than  the $241 million  claimed).   DOJ  stipulated Co  liability  in
35  cases resulting  In  awards  of $13 million.  Sixteen judgments  have
been for plaintiffs (most are being appealed) and  74 judgments have
been for the defendant.^^

E.   Indemnity in  the Form of  an Ongoing  Insurance  Program

     1.  Arts and  Artifacts

        The  Arts  and Artifacts Indemnity Act113 enables  the  federal
government to indemnify  American museums  for losses  Incurred In  exhi-
biting  internationally  loaned art  or artifacts.  It  was  passed after
the  previous Congress enacted special  legislation  for two  specific
exhibitions.  Interested parties apparently  convinced Congress that
the  problem  needed a more institutionalized  solution.  The cost  of
insurance had grown to 2/3 to 3/4  of the  total cost  of putting on  an
exhibit, and many institutions could not afford such premiums.*^

        The  program is administered under regulations promulgated  by
the  National Endowment for the Arts.  A  rigorous application process
insures that most of the 40 final  applicants a year  are  accepted,
because those who could  not succeed are weeded out before  they com*
plete the process.  Applications concern such things as  packing,
shipping, climate control, and security arrangements rather  than
aethetic merit are or political significance.  The Endowment's Inter-
est  in  risk  reduction prompts requests to add night  guards and impose
other conditions.  Small institutions which  could  not handle the
stringent requirements alone  often go  to the International Exhibition
Foundation which  gives them advise as well as grants.  The exhibitor's
valuation of the  objects is reviewed by an indemnity advisory  panel
and  then by  the Federal  Council on Arts and  the Humanities.  A con-
tract between the Council and the museum pledges the full  faith  and
credit  of the United States.  Funding  is provided  through  special
appropriations.  When a  loss  occurs it will  be investigated  by the
government and an assessment  certified to Congress.  So  far, no  losses
have exceeded the amount of the deductible.

        The  federal indemnification program does not insure  the  entire
amount  of the exhibit.   The institutions are required to obtain  insur-
ance from private sources to  cover a deductible (which ranges  from
$15,000-$50,000 depending on  the value of the exhibit),  and  the  risks
in excess of the  federal limit of $50 million per  exhibit.  The  pro-
gram may not obligate more than $400 million at any  one  time.
Although no  payments have yet been made, the fact  that the museums do
not have to  purchase insurance for the amount covered by federal
                                 A-25

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Appendix A
 indemnification had saved  them an estimated $800 million  in  insurance
 premiums by  the summer of  198I.11*

    2.  Defense Contracts

        Although a contingent and uncertain liability  like indemnifi-
 cation  is usually prohibited by the Anti-Deficiency Act,  Congress  and
 the President have made exceptions for contracts that  "facilitate  the
 national defense" and are  "unusually hazardous or nuclear in
 nature."I1*1  Evidently the authority to use indemnification  clauses  in
 such contracts has been used frequently, but no claims have  actually
 been paid out by the government.  In this case also, the  promise of
 the federal  government has been sufficient to accomplish  the goal  of
 obtaining services and materials, important to the national  defense,
 that would otherwise not be obtainable because of a possibly unaccep-
 table risk to the manufacturer.

        Some agencies have apparently agreed to indemnify even without
 express authority if the contractors are needed to perform a vital
 service, such as evacuating plane loads of people from Viet  Nam.   The
 Comptroller General sanctioned one such use of indemnification in  a    .
 contract between the General Services Administration and  a public
 utility.117

    3.  Non-Defense Contractors

        Some agencies, arguably within the scope of the "unusually
 hazardous" exception carved out by the Executive Order, have not used
 it because they did not want to label their activities.   This has  been
 a particular problem for NASA.  Its contractors demand some  protection
 against the possible catastrophic loss connected with  an  event such  as
 the Space Shuttle crashing In a populated area.  In its authorization
 of 1981, NASA received a special authority to indemnify users of the
 space shuttle against claims for property damage, death or injury  to
 the extent the claims are not compensated by liability insurance,  and
 to the extent that they do not result from negligence  or  willful mis-
 conduct by the user.

        An interagency task force, co-sponsored by the Office of
 Federal Procurement Policy and NASA, has recently completed  its draft
 report and recommended expansion of indemnification authority to cover
 possibilities of catastrophic loss, which it defines as loss beyond
 that can be covered by reasonably available insurance, but not neces-
 sarily resulting from "unusually hazardous" activity.11**  The National
Association of Manufacturers is sponsoring a related bill to indemnify
 all suppliers of products to the government.11^

        EPA has had several requests from contractors  for indemnifica-
 tion provisions in their contracts with the Agency.  A potential "host
 site" asked that the contractors who want to test new  pollution con-
                                 A-26

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Appendix A
trol equipment In  its plant be Indemnified by  the  government against
•possible damage  to  the plant or Interrupted operations.  This  request
was denied.  In  at  least one case, EPA paid the  insurance premiums on
a special policy for a contractor conducting field operations  on haz-
ardous material  cleanup.  The premium cost $200,000 for $1,000,000
worth of coverage.

        In one case EPA has agreed to directly indemnify contractors
hired to clean up hazardous waste sites under  Superfund.  Private
insurance for the contractors would have added 102 to the cost of the
contracts.  (Insurance coverage of $10,000,000 would have cost one
contractor $400,000 for one year, and another  $320,000 for a
$25,000,000 coverage for a year.)120  EPA designed an indemnification
clause to avoid Anti-Deficiency Act problems.121  The clause covers
all damages, even those arising from contractor negligence but, it is
conditioned on the availability of funds of the time a claim is made,
with the specific proviso that EPA will not promise to seek funds, and
that Congress is under no obligation to provide them.  Apparently this
was sufficient to satisfy the concerns of the  contractors.122  The
Indemnity clauses are excess liability only, all contractors are
required to purchase one million dollars of commercial liability
insurance which must be exhausted first.
                                 A-27

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Appendix A
                       FOOTNOTES TO APPENDIX A

    177 Am. Jur. 2d "United States" § 117 (1975); 91 C.J.S. "United
States" § 184 (1955).

    2See generally 35 Am. Jur. 2d "Federal Tort Claims Act" §§ 1 et
seq. (1967); Annot., "Federal Tort Claims Act," 1 A.L.R.2d 222, § 1
(1948); Jayson, Handling Federal Tort Claims (Mathew Bender 1964);
H.R. Rep. 1287, 79th Cong., 1st Sess. (1945); H.R. Rep. 2245, 77th
Cong., 2d Sesa. (1942); Hearings on Bills to Provide for the
Adjustment of Certain Tort Claims Against the United States, H.R.
5373 and H.R. 6463. House Judiciary Committee. 77th Cong., 2d Sess.
(1942); and Tort Claims Against the United States, Subcommittee of the
Senate Judiciary Committee, 76th Cong., 1st Sess. (1940).

    Specifically, 28 U.S.C. § 1346(b) confers jurisdiction on the
federal district courts and under 28 U.S.C. §§ 2671 et seq. the United
States has consented to suit, subject to the following thirteen excep-
tions under 28 U.S.C. § 2680:

                 (a)  Any claim based upon an act or omis-
              sion of an employee of the Government, exer-
              cising due care, in the execution of a statute
              or regulation, whether or not such statute or
              regulation be valid, or based upon the exer-
              cise or performance or the failure to exercise
              or perform a discretionary function or duty on
              the part of a federal agency or an employee of
              the Government, whether or not the discretion
              involved be abused.

                 (b)  Any claim arising out of the loss,
              miscarriage, or negligent transmission of let-
              ters or postal matter.

                 (c)  Any claim arising in respect of the
              assessment or collection of any tax or customs
              duty, or the detention of any goods or mer-
              chandise by any officer of customs or excise
              or any other law enforcement officer.

                 (d)  Any claim for which a remedy is pro-
              vided by sections 741-752, 781-790 of Title
              46,  relating to claims or suits in admiralty
              against the United States.

                 (e)  Any claim arising out of an act or
              omission of any employee of the Government in
              administering the provisions of sections 1-31
              of Title 50, Appendix.
                                 A-28

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix A
                  (f)  Any claim  for damages caused by  the
              imposition or establishment of a quarantine by
              the United States.

                  (g)  [Repealed]

                  (h)  Any claim  arising out of assault,
              battery, false imprisonment, false arrest,
              malicious prosecution, abuse of process,
              libel, slander, misrepresentation, deceit, or
              interference with  contract rights.  Provided,
              That, with regard  to acts or omissions of
              investigative or law enforcement officers of
              the United States  Government, the provisions
              of  this chapter and section 1346(b) of this
              title shall apply  to any claim arising on or
              after the date of  the enactment of this
              proviso, out of assault, battery, false
              imprisonment, false arrest, abuse of process,
              or malicious prosecution.  For the purpose of
              this subsection, "investigative or law
              enforcement officer" means any officer of the
              United States who  is empowered by law to exe-
              cute searches, to  seize evidence, or to make
              arrests for violations of Federal law.

                 (i)  Any claim  for damages caused by the
              fiscal operations  of the Treasury or by the
              regulation of the  monetary system.

                 (j)  Any claim  arising out of the combatant
              activities of the  military or naval forces, or
              the Coast Guard, during time of war.

                 (k)  Any claim  arising in a foreign
              country.

                 (1)  Any claim arising from the activities
              of the Tennessee Valley Authority.

                 (m)  Any claim arising from the activities
              of the Panama Canal Company.

                 (n)  Any claim arising from the activities
              of a Federal land bank,  a Federal intermediate
              credit bank, or a bank for cooperatives.

    ^In adjusting claims administratively, agency heads must follow
any regulations prescribed by the Attorney General, and obtain his
prior written approval for any award greater than $25,000*  If admi-
                                 A-29

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix A
 nistrative  adjustment  proves  unsuccessful  and a  lawsuit  if  filed, the
 Attorney  General,  or a designee  of  the  Attorney  General, may settle
 the  case  out  of  court.

     4Supra  note  2.  28 U.S.C.  §  2680(h).

     518 U.S.C. § 2680(a).   See  Reynolds,  "The Discretionary Function
 Exception of  the Federal Tort  Claims  Act," 57 Geo. L.J.  81  (1968); and
 James, "The Federal Tort Claims  Act and the Discretionary Function
 Exception:  The  Sluggish Retreat of an  Ancient Immunity,"   10 U. Fla.
 L. Rev. 184 (1957).

     6Blessing v. United States.  447 F.  Supp. 1160, 1178  (E.D. Pa.
 1978).

     7See  generally. 35  Am.  Jur.  2d  "Federal Tort Claims  Act" §§ 15 et^
 seq. (1967);  Annot., "FTCA-Permits, etc.," 35 A.L.R. Fed. 481 (1977);
 Annot., "Law  Enforcement as Discretionary," 36 A.L.R.  Fed. 240
 (1978); Annot.,  "Maintenance of  Public  Property," 37 A.L.R. Fed. 537
 (1978); Annot.,  "Federal Tort  Claims  Act," 99 A.L.R.2d 1016 (1965);
 Annot., "FTCA-Exceptions,"  6 L.  Ed. 2d  1428 (1962).

     8For  example,  in Eastern Airlines v. Union Trust Co., 221 F.2d 62
 (D.C. Cir.  1955),  it was held  that the  government's determination of
 the  location  of an air  traffic control  tower is a discretionary
 planning  decision which falls within  the discretionary function excep-
 tion to the FTCA.  However, an operator's negligence in  clearing two
 planes for  landing on  the same runway at the same time is not pro-
 tected by the discretionary function  exception.

     'For  example, a party may  be  entitled to rely upon the
 government's  non-negligent  handling of  a rescue operation at sea or
 the  proper  enforcement  of mine safety standards under a  safety inspec-
 tion program.  See, e.g., Eastern Airlines, id. and Raymer v. United
 States, 482 F. Supp. 432 (W.D. Ky. 1979).

    10Barton v. United  States. 609 F.2d 977 (10th Cir. 1979)
 (temporary  discontinuance of livestock  grazing permits, Bureau of Land
Management); Thompson v. United  States. 592 F.2d 1104 (9th Cir. 1979)
 (permit to  sponsor motorcycle  race on public property, Bureau of Land
Management); Myers & Myers, Inc.  v. United States Postal Service, 527
F.2d 1252 (2d Cir. 1975) (award  of transportation contract); Coast-
wise Packet Co. v. United States, 398 F.2d 77 (1st Cir.  1968), cert.
denied, 393 U.S. 937 (1968) (certificate of inspection, Coast Guard);
Boruski v. Division of  Corp. Finance, 321 F. Supp. 1273  (S.D.N.Y.
 1971) (registration approval, Securities and Exchange Commission);
Hooper v. United States, 331 F.  Supp. 1056 (D. Conn. 1971) (permit to
construct power-generating  station, Corps of Engineers); Marr v.
United States, 307 F.   Supp. 930  (E.D.  Okla. 1969) (pilot's license
and certificate of convenience and necessity, Civil Aeronautics
Board).
                                 A-30

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix A
     uln  Griffin  v. United States. 500 F.2d 1059  (3d Clr.  1974), a
 decision  involving  negligent  inspection and approval of oral polio
 vaccine,  the  court  found  that  the inspector's  action was of a
 non-policy, professional  nature and  that  the discretionary function
 exception was  not applicable.

     In  a  mine  safety  inspection case the  discretionary function excep-
 tion was  held  not applicable  to protect the government against liabi-
 lity resulting from injury when an inspector allowed an extension of
 time for  the  correction of an  obviously hazardous condition.  Raymer
 v. United States, supra note 9.  Noting the clear statutory mandate
 for  vigorous  enforcement, the  court held  that  the inspector's function
 was  operational in that he had no discretion to grant a time extension
 and  he  was negligent  to do so.

     1228  U.S.C. § 2680 (h).  United States v. Neustadt. 366 U.S. 696
 (1961).   See generally Tort Claims Against the United States, Subcom-
 mittee  of the  Senate  Judiciary Committee, 76th Cong., 1st Sess. 39
 (1940); 35  Am. Jur.  2d "Federal Tort Claims Act" § 46 (1967); Annot.,
 "FTCA-Deceit," 30 A.L.R. Fed. 421 (1976); Annot., "FTCA-Exceptions," 6
 L. Ed.  2d 1465  (1962).

     "id..

     14Cenna v. United States. 402 F.2d 168 (3d Cir. 1968).
            has been a particular reluctance to apply the
misrepresentation exception to personal injury claims of medical
malpractice or negligent flight Information.  United States v.
Neustadt, 366 U.S. 696 (1961); Redmond v. United States, 518 F.2d 811
(7th Cir. 1975); Marlval. Inc. v. Planes. Inc.. 306 F. Supp. 855 (N.D.
Ga. 1966).

    16Ingham v. Eastern Airlines. Inc.. 373 F.2d 227 (2d Cir. 1967),
cert, denied, United States v. Ingham, 389 U.S. 931 (1967); United
Air Lines. Inc. v. Wiener, 335 F.2d 379 (9th Cir. 1964), cert.
dismissed.. 379 U.S. 951 (1964);

    17Ramirez v. United States. 567 F.2d 854 (9th Cir. 1977).
          example, in medical malpractice cases an erroneous diagnosis
communicated to the patient is simply a misrepresentation and falls
within the exception to the waiver of immunity.  If the physician were
simply a diagnostic consultant and not responsible for the care of the
patient, the government would not be liable for the misrepresentation.
But if, as is more often the case, the diagnosing physician is also
the treating physician, who is under an affirmative duty to give
proper treatment, liability could be based on the negligent conduct of
the physician in treating the patient.  Scanwell Laboratories. Inc.
v. Thomas, 521 F.2d 941 (D.C. Cir. 1975); Covington v. United States.
303 F. Supp. 1145 (N.D. Miss. 1969).
                                 A-31

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix A
          a case  where  the  exception was found applicable,  a grain
 importer unsuccessfully  claimed  that the government had negligently
 processed a request  for  amendments  to its import permits and had
 failed to advise of  a  written  policy prohibiting the types of imports
 which he planned to  ship to  the  United States.  Because of these
 alleged events,  the  claimant had its corn shipped to this  country only
 to  have it destroyed upon  arrival.   Cargill,  Inc. v. United States,
 426 F.  Supp.  127 (D. Minn. 1976).
           example  of  a  taking  is  the  situation in Kaiser Aetna v.
United  States, 44  U.S.  164  (1979),  in which the Supreme Court  deter-
mined under  the  facts of  the case that- the government could not, with-
out  paying compensation,  force  the  petitioner  to admit the  public  to  a
private lagoon which  had  been  connected to a public  bay. A second
taking  example is  Pete  v. United  States,  531 F.2d 1018 (Ct. Cl. 1976),
in which the government condemned all the land surrounding  a lake  and
prohibited use of  gasoline  powered  engines on  the lake.  The court
concluded that the government's action constituted inverse  condem-
nation  compensable under  the Fifth  Amendment because it effectively
destroyed the usefulness  of three large houseboats permanently placed
upon the lake.  This  was  not a pure regulatory taking, though, because
the  regulatory restriction  accompanied the physical  taking  of  real   *
estate.   A third example  is Hernandez v.  City  of Lafayette, 643 F.2d
1188 (5th Cir. 1981), in  which the  Court  of Appeals  remanded for trial
a case  where a city allegedly  took  property by refusing to  rezone  land
because  it was going  to build a highway through the  property and
wanted  to keep the depressed value  of the land that  the current zoning
represented.

     20aSweet v. Rechel. 159 U.S.  380  (1895).  See 58 Am.  Jur.  2d
"Nuisance" § 206 (1971);  35 Am. Jur.  2d "Food"HT65-66 (1967).

     21South Terminal  Corp. v. EPA.  504 F.2d 646,  678 (1st Cir.  1974)
(transportation control plan which  mandated a  40Z reduction in
available  off-street  parking spaces held  not a taking).

     22Id.  at 679.

     23Andrus v. Allard. 444 U.S.  51,  100  S.  Ct.  318,  326 (1979)
(substantial restriction on Indian  artifacts containing feathers of
protected  birds not considered a  taking because  owner continued to be
allowed  to possess and  transport  property,  to  donate or devise the
protected  birds and could exhibit the artifacts  for  an admission
price).  The court in And r us also -stated:

              [T]he denial of one traditional  property right
              does not always amount  to a taking.  At least
              where an owner possesses a  full  "bundle" of
              property  rights, the  destruction of one
              "strand" of the bundle  is not a  taking,
                                A-32

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix  A
               because  the  aggregate  must  be  viewed  in  its
               entirety.  .  .  When  we  review regulation,  a
               reduction  in the  value of  property  is  not
               necessarily  equated with a  taking.  .  . At any
               rate,  loss of  future profits — unaccompanied  by
               any  physical property  restriction — provides  a
               slender  reed upon which to  rest  a takings
               claim.   Prediction  of  profitability is essen-
               tially a matter of  reasoned  speculation  that
               courts are not especially competent to per-
               form.  Further, perhaps because  of  Its very
               uncertainty, the  interest in anticipated  gains
               has  traditionally been viewed  as less  compel-
               ling  than other property-related interests.
Id.  See Appendix A  page A-9, A-10.
         Bosselman, D. Callies & J. Banta, The Taking Issue;  An
Analysis of the Constitutional Limits on Land Use Control  (Gov't
Printing Office, Washington, D.C.  1973).

    25Mugler v. Kansas. 123 U.S. 623 (1887).

    26The Court in Mugler  stressed the fact that there was no physical
invasion of property, ruling there was no taking since it was within
the government's power to  regulate property to eliminate a nuisance.
The Court stated that:

              the destruction of property which is  itself a
              public nuisance, or  the prohibition of its use
              in a particular way, whereby its value becomes
              depreciated  is very  different from taking pro-
              perty for public use. ... In the one case, a
              nuisance only is abated; in the other, unof-
              fending property is  taken away from an inno-
              cent owner.

Id. at 668-69.

    27Fennsylvanla Coal Co. v. Mahon, 260 U.S. 393, 413 (1922).  The
Court stated:

              One fact for consideration in determining such
              limits is the extent of the diminution.  When
              It reaches a certain magnitude, in most if not
              in all cases there must be an exercise of emi-
              nent domain and compensation to sustain the
              act.  So the question depends upon the partic-
              ular facts.  The greatest weight is given to
              the judgment of the  legislature, but  it always
                                 A-33

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Appendix A
               Is open to  interested parties to contend that
               the  legislature has gone beyond its constitu-
               tional power.

    28Kaiser Aetna v. United States. 444 U.S. 164 (1979); Andrus v.
Allard, supra  note 23; Penn Central Transportation Co. v. City of New
York. 438 U.S. 104 (1978); Goldblatt v. Town of Hempstead, 369 U.S.
590 (1962).  For a recent overview of the taking issue, see Note,
"Reexamining the Supreme  Court's View of the Taking Clause," 58 Tex.
L. Rev. 1447 (1980).  See also Kanner, "The Consequence of Taking
Property by Regulation." 24 Prac. Law. 65 (1978).  For an evaluation
of various theoretical models for analyzing the taking question, see
Berger, "A Policy Analysis of the Taking Problem," 49 N.Y.U.L. Rev.
165 (1974).                  c

    2^Supra note 27.

    30260 U.S. at 413.

    31Id. at 413-14.

    32United States v. Central Eureka Mining Co.. 357 U.S. 155 (1958).

    33Id._ at 168.

        >ra note 23.
        W^BIm

      3Supra note 23.

    36Agins v. City of Tiburon. 100 S. Ct. 2138 (1980). See also
Goldblatt v. Town of Hempstead, 369 U.S. 590 (1960) (prohibition of
excavation of  sand and gravel below water table not a taking);  Penn
Central Transportation Co. v. City of New York, 438 U.S. 104 (1978)
(denial of right to exploit air space by building office building
above Grand Central Station not a taking).

    37Sierra Club v. EPA, 540 F.2d 1114 (D.C. Cir. 1976).  See also
Chesapeak Bay Village. Inc. v.  Costle. 502 F. Supp. 213 (D. Md. 1980)
(no taking where plaintiff's plans to develop land into subdivisions
jeopardized because of insufficient sewer facilities due to federal
government giving insufficient  grant for sewage treatment facility);
and Creppel v. U.S. Army Corps  of Engineers, 500 F. Supp. 1108 (E.D.
La. 1980) (taking claim rejected in action to compel Corps of
Engineers to authorize flood control project in accordance with origi-
nal plans).

    38Supra note 22.

    39Chevron Chemical Co. v. Costle. 641 F.2d 104 (3d Cir. 1981),
cert,  denied.  101 S. Ct. 3110 (1981) (concerning §§ 3(c)(l)(D) and 10
                                 A-34

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Appendix A
 of FIFRA).   See  also  Mobay  v.  Costle,  517  F.  Supp.  252  (W.D.  Pa.,  No.
 CA 79-591D,  June 12,  1981),  which  expressly followed  the  holding  of
 the Chevron  case;  and Union  Carbide  Agricultural  Products  Co.  v.
 Gorsch  (S.D.N'.Y.,  No, 76 Civ.  2913),  in  which a  preliminary  injunction
 issued  by  the  district  court was vacated on appeal  by the  Second
 Circuit.

     40Hodel  v. Virginia Surface Mining & Reclamation  Ass'n,
 452 U.S. 264,  101  S.  Ct. 2352  (1981)  (steep slopes  provision  did  not
 prohibit surface mining, but only  regulates conditions  of  performing
 mining  operations).   See also  Hodel  v. Indiana, 452 U.S.  314,  101  S.
 Ct.  2376 (1981)  (same situation as Hodel above except challenge cen-
 tered upon prime farmland requirement);  Nance v.  EPA, 645  F.2d 701
 (9th Cir. 1981)  (taking issue  not  ripe because not  yet  established
 that strip mining  on  Northern  Cheyenne Tribe's reservation is  subject
 to  PSD  nor that  the land is  suitable  for strip mining).  See  also San
 Diego Gas &  Electric  Co. v.  City of  San  Diego. 450  U.S. 621,  101  S.
 Ct.  1287 (1981)  (Supreme Court found  5-4 in challenge to city's open
 space plan and rezonlng that California  state court decision  was  not
 final in that  California court decided monetary damages were  not
 appropriate  but  not if  there was indeed  a  taking).

     A1United States v. Realty  Co.. 163 U.S. 427,  440  (1896).   The
 Supreme Court  has  recently reaffirmed  the  authority of  Congress to
 define  and pay the debts of  the United States, by appropriation or by
 waiving an otherwise  valid defense to  a  claim against the  government.
 Sioux Nation v.  United States. 448 U.S.  371,  100  S. Ct. 2716  (1980).
 The  right to petition the government  for redress  of grievances Is also
 cited as authority.

     42Those  of the House are codified In the  Rules  of the  Subcommittee
 on Administrative Law and Governmental Relations, House Committee on
 the  Judiciary.

     ^Telephone  conversation on March 26,  1982 with Bill Shattuck,
 Counsel to House Judiciary Committee, Subcommittee  on Administrative
 Law  and Governmental  Relations.  The Comptroller  General may  also
 recommend bills, though the  authority is rarely used, 31 U.S.C. § 236.

     44Note,  "Private  Bills in  Congress," 79 Harv. L. Rev.  1684, 1689
 (1966).
         one member objects strongly to a bill, he can usually per-
suade one of his colleagues to object along with him.  Thus, in prac
tice a single objection can kill a private bill, according to
Shattuck, supra note 43.

    46In the 95th Congress 1,552 private bills were introduced, 283
passed.  In the 96th Congress 1,334 were introduced, of which 181
passed.  The 97th Congress is not yet over, but so far 962 private
                                 A-35

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix A
 bills have been introduced  and  75  passed.   The  percent  passing  has
 dropped  from 18%,  to  13.5%  to  less than  8X.

     ^Id. , Private Bills, supra note  44.   For example,  the  CPSC
 testified  in favor of relief for Marlin  Toy Co.
           example,  although 67%  of  the  private  bills  introduced  in the
 97th  Congress  concerned  immigration,  85Z  of  those  passed  were  immigra-
 tion  bills.  See also Private Bills,  supra note 44 at 1693.

    ^'Apparently only six vetoes of private  bills  have been
 overridden, none of them in the  last-fifty years.   Id. at 1693.

    50ld.  at 1701.       °

    51Sup_ra note 43.

    32Act  of Feb. 24, 1855, ch.  122,  10 Stat. 612.

    53Cong. Globe,  37th  Cong., 2d Sess.,  App. 2 (1862).

    54Act  of March  3, 1863, ch.  92 §  5, 12 Stat. 765,  766.  Appeal /s
 now available  only  on writ of certiorari.

    "Repealed after the Supreme Court refused  to  review  a judgment
 on the grounds that Congress's remaining  power  over the court's  Judg-
 ments was  inconsistent with its  exercise  of  judical power.  Glidden v.
 Zdanok. 370 U.S. 530, 554 (1962).

    5631 U.S.C. § 724a.
         U.S.C. § 1491.  The district courts have been given concur-
rent jurisdication on these cases where the claim is less  than
$10,000.  29 U.S.C. § 1346(a)(2).

    ^However, the court of claims may hear appeals of FTCA cases from
federal district courts with the consent of appellees.  28 U.S.C.
§ 1504.

    59"Annual Report to Congress, January 25, 1982" by Office of the
Clerk, Court of Claims.

    60Glidden, supra note 55.

    ^In cases falling under general jurisdiction, trial commissioners
hold hearings and make recommendations to the court.  28 U.S.C. § 792
(1925).

    62Glidden, supra note 55.
                                 A-36

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Appendix A
               "Congressional Reference Cases in the United States
Court  of  Claims:  A Historical and Current Perspective, 25 Am. U. L.
Rev. 595  (1976).

    6428  U.S.C. § 2509(c); 28 U.S.C. § 1492.  Congressional reference
cases  are tried under rules which closely follow the regular rules of
the court.  28 U.S.C. § 2509(b).  For an explanation of procedure, see
Glosser,  supra note 63, at 605-17.

    "For more detail on procedure, see Glosser, id.

    66M.T. Bennett, "Private Claims and Congressional References," 9
A.F. Jag  L. Rev. No. 6 (Nov. -Dec. 1967)

    "'Telephone conversations on March 26, 1982 with Linda Nucessian,
Counsel to Subcommittee on Agency Administration, Senate Judiciary
Committee and Frank T. Peartree, Clerk, U.S. Court of Claims.

    68113 Ct. Cl. 658, 667 (1949).  Though the language is clear,
Burkhardt has caused confusion because the court found that the plain-
tiffs  had more than a merely equitable or honorable obligation.  The
more expansive definition was not necessary to reach the holding.

    69168 Ct. Claims 318, Cong. Ref. No. 11-58 (1964).  In Drake
America Corp. v. United States for example, the court found that a
claim  for additional compensation for a contract to develop a high-
speed  snow plow for the Air Force had neither a legal nor an equitable
basis  within the meaning of the statute.  The record did not support
the plaintiff's claim that it reasonably relied to its detriment on a
promise that additional funds would be approved, and the court found
that the  plaintiff had been sufficiently compensated for the work
performed.
         , Innocent Victims of the Occupation of Wounded Knee, South
Dakota v. United States. Cong. Ref. No. 4076 (June 10, 1981); Burt v»
United States. 199 Ct. Cl. 897; Glosser, supra note 63 at 620-22.

    71Cherokee Nation v. United States. 270 U.S. 476 (1926), discussed
in Sioux Nation v. United States, supra note 41.

    72Sioux Nation, id. at 397.

    73Mizokaml v. United States. 118 Ct. Cl. 736, 414 F.2d 1375
(1969).

    74Pope v. United States. 323 U.S. 1 (1944) discussed In Sioux
Nation, supra note 41, at 399.

    7 ^s. 823 discussed supra at page A-22.
                                 A-37  '

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Appendix  A
     7621  U.S.C.  §  lU(a),  134(d)
     ''"Indemnification  Under  Animal Disease  Control  Programs with
 Special  Emphasis  on  Foot-and-Mouth Disease,"  Nasser A. Aulaqi  and
 W.B.  Sundquist, Department  of Agricultural and Applied Economics,
 University  of  Minnesota,  Economic Report ER  77-2, February  1977, at 4.

    ^Telephone conversation  with Dr. M.J. Tillery,  USDA Animal, Plant
 Health and  Inspection Service.

    799  C.F.R. §§  50-56.
    81See Julius Goldman' c Egg City. 566 F.2d 1096  (1977).

    ^Estimate by Division of Veterinary Services USDA, contained in
Background Draft by  ICF, Inc. "Costs Associated with USDA Animal
Disease Indemnification Programs" at 6.

    837 U.S.C. 450J.

    8A7 U.S.C. 135b.

    "Although less  harmful to humans, and less persistant in the
environment, they are more damaging to bees.

    ^Figures from a telephone conversation with Gerald Schiermeyer,
Agricultural Stabilization and Conservation Service, USDA.

    87Telephone conversation on July 12, 1982 with Marcy Farden,
legislative aid to Rep. Akaka.

    887 C.F.R. § 760.

    89Gellhorn, "Adverse Publicity by Administrative Agencies," 86
Harv. L. Rev. 1380, 1408 (1973) (quoting from internal FDA
memorandum) .
           year an amount equal to 30 percent of the gross receipts
from duties collected under the customs law the proceeding year is
appropriated to the fund authorized by 7 U.S.C. § 612c.  It is used to
encourage agricultural exports, and domestic consumption, and to
"reestablish farmer's purchasing power."  The food stamp and school
lunch programs are run under the authority of this section.
Approximately $8.5 million was paid to 12 claimants representing 1,215
growers, based on a schedule of prices per barrel of cranberries.

    91Gellhorn, supra note 89 at 1408-10.  The enabling legislation of
the Consumer Product Safety Commission requires notice to the parties
similar announcements on product safety are made.  15 U.S.C.  § 2055.
                                 A-38

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Appendix A
           of the following description Is based on Mizokami v. U.S.,
414 F.2d 1375, 188 Ct. Cl. 736 (1969).

    93Priv. L. 88-346, 78 Stat. 1195 (1964).

    9438 Fed. Reg. 29400, 29404 (1973).

    95S. 3666, 120 Cong. Rec. 34000 (1974); H.R. 17652, 120 Cong. Rec,
41832-33 (1974).

    96Cong. Ref. Nos. 2-74 & 1-75, (Dec. 19, 1978).

    9715 U.S.C. 2054(h). P.L. 94-284.

              (h) Civil action against the United States

                Subsections (a) and (h) of section 2680 of
              title 28 do not prohibit the bringing of a
              civil action on a claim against the United
              States which —

                  (1) is based upon —

                     (A)  misrepresentation or deceit before
                  January 1, 1978, on the part of the Com-
                  mission or any employee thereof, or

                     (B)  any exercise or performance, or
                  failure to exercise or perform, a discre-
                  tionary function on the part of the Com-
                  mission or any employee thereof before
                  January 1, 1978, which exercise, perform-
                  ance, or failure was grossly negligent;
                  and

                  (2) is not made with respect to any agency
              action (as defined in section 551(13) of title
              5).

              In the case of a civil action on a claim based
              upon the exercise or performance of, or fail-
              ure to exercise or perform, a discretionary
              function, no judgment may be entered against
              the United States unless the court in which
              such action was brought determines (based upon
              consideration of all the relevant circum-
              stances, Including the statutory responsibil-
              ity of the Commission and the public interest
              in encouraging rather than inhibiting the
              exercise of discretion) that such exercise,
                                 A-39

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix A
               performance,  or  failure  to  exercise  or  perform
               was  unreasonable.

 (Emphasis  added.)

     ^Conversation with Mana Jennings,  Office  of General  Counsel,
 CPSC.

     ^FF 3-71, FF  5-74:  The working paper,  "Tris  Ban"  prepared  for
 the  Regulatory Impacts Branch, OTS by The Conservation  Foundation
 notes  only 40-502  of  the garments sized 12 months  to  6X used  the flame
 retardant  Tris to  meet the  standard.  After JTris was  banned,  clothing
 manufacturers  had  to  use a  more expensive chemical flame  retardant for
 a  short time,  but  by  1978 they tfere meeting  flammability  standards by
 using  inherently flame- retardant fabrics  at  costs  comparable  to  Tris.

     1 ^Telephone conversation with Mana Jennings,  Office  of General
 Counsel, CPSC, March  1982.

     1 01- The requirement to repurchase banned  hazardous substances is no
 longer automatic.  15 U.S.C. § 1261.  The 1981 Authorization  of  CPSC
 added an informal  adjudicatory hearing  on which the Agency order to
 repurchase must be based.

     102Supra note  100.

     103Supra note  99, and S. Rep. 97-130,  accompanying  S. 823.
        . 823 was passed by the Senate in June of 1981; the House
Judiciary Subcommittee on Administrative Law held hearings on June 16,
1982.
        .R. 4264, H.R. 4180, Cyclamatea Compensation;  Hearings Before
Subcommittee No. 2 of the House Committee of Judiciary, 92d Cong., 1st
Sess. 44 (1971).
                the legislation never passed,  it raised  issues  that
were deemed important enough to be considered  by high level officials
in a series of meetings and memos.  A memorandum for the Honorable
John C. Whitaker, The White House, on "Indemnification of Business
Losses Arising from Federal Regulatory Activities, (March 15, 1971)"
signed by Wilmot R. Hastings, General Counsel  recounted  some of this
activity, and the positions of various participants, including John
Dean, Richard Kleindiest and Jim Lynn.

    107S. Res. 225 referred to the Court of Claims S. 1894 and S. Rpt.
95-576 on Nov. 28, 1977.

    10^Briefs are filed at Court of Claims.  According to defendant's
final brief, the proposed rule was published two months  before the
                                 A-40

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix A
 Association had to make a decision  on  how to  pack that  year's crop.
 Apparently the  Association discussed  the  situation with many  people,
 including  its bankers.   One reason  that  it  may  have decided  to go
 ahead  and  take  the risk was that  for  the  period just before  the ban,
 15%  of the sales  of the Association involved  cyclamate-packed
 products,  but they contributed  50%  of  the profits.

     1°942  U.S.C.  § 247(b),  P.L, 94-380.
            one  account  of  the  political,  professional,  and  economic
 stakes  in  the dispute over a swine  flue vaccination  program,  see  The
 Swine Flu  Affair; Decision-Making on a Slippery Disease, Richard  E.
 Neustadt and Harvey V.  Fineberg, M.D.  According  to  Neustadt  the  impe-
 tus  for swift passage of the swine  flu act  (through  both Houses and
 signed  by  Ford  in two weeks) was a  feared link to Legionnaire's
 Disease.

     ^Telephone conversation  with  Jeffrey  Axelrod,  DOJ.

     112!d_L

     11320  U.S.C. 971. 89 Stat. 844  (1976).

     1141975 U.S. Cong,  and Admin. News 1640.

     1 ^Telephone conversation  with  Alice Martin, Indemnification
 Administrator for National Endowment for the Arts, February 1982.

     11650 U.S.C. § 1431 and Executive Order 10789.

     11759 Comp. Gen. 705 (Sept. 3,  1980).

     118"Draft Report of the OFPP Interagency Task Force on Indemnifi-
 cation," (January 28, 1982).

     119H.R. 1504; cf. Stencel v. United States. 431 U.S. 66 (1977).
                  from Paul Martin, Acting Director Procurement and
Contracts Division to William Coleman, Indemnification Task Group,
OFPP, September 8, 1981.

    1 ^Internal EPA Memorandum from Don Nantkes, OGC to Paul Martin,
OTC, (June 28, 1981).

    122Telephone conversation on May 26, 1982 with Pamela John, EPA,
Procurement Contracts Management Division.
                                 A-41

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix  B
                             APPENDIX B

      REGULATORY AND LEGISLATIVE ALTERNATIVES TO INDEMNIFICATION


                                                                 Page

I.     Introduction	B-2

II.    The Operation Of Alternatives	B-3

       A.  Alternative Means of Eliminating Harms	B-3

          1.  Financial Assistance	r-	B-3
          2.  Exceptions and Waivers	B-4
          3.  Facilitated Participation and Review	B-5

       B.  Alternative Means of Spreading or Shifting Harms.  .  .  B-6

          1.  Restoration Funds 	  B-6
          2.  Limitation of Liability	B-7

       C.  Alternative Means of Reducing the Severity
          of Harms	B-8

          1.  Postponement of Compliance Deadlines	B-8
          2.  Forebearance with Publicity 	  B-9

       D.  Alternative Means of Improving Ability to Absorb
          Harms	B-9

          1.  Education and Information Transfer	B-9
          2.  Resource and Technology Pooling  	  B-10
          3.  Partial Financial Assistance	B-ll

III.   Legislative Treatment Of Loss Situations	B-12

      A.  Emergency Powers	B-12
       B.  Change of Regulatory Policy 	  B-13
       C.   Tort Situations Potentially Not Covered Under the
          Federal Tort Claims Act:  Delays and Ineffective
          EPA Action; Unreasonable Enforcement; and Disclosure
          of Confidential Business Information	B-13
      D.  Conflicting Requirements	B-14
      E.  The Incentive Situation	B-14

IV.    A Framework For Choosing Between Indemnification and
       Alternative Relief Mechanism 	  B-16

Table  I—Will an Alternative Produce a Remedial Result
         Comparable to Indemnification? 	  B-17

Footnotes 	 ...... 	 .....  B-18
                                      •a

                                 B-l  :

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix B
                          I.  INTRODUCTION
    One important corollary to the general  tendency against  indemnifi-
cation by the government is that there are  numerous alternative mecha-
nisms available to address many of the same losses, concerns, or
problems, to which indemnification could be made  to apply.   While
indemnification has rarely been provided in federal statutes and
administrative programs, some of the available alternatives  are quite
common.

    In this appendix, several major alternatives  to indemnification
are identified and defined.  Part II of the appendix describes the
operation of ten important alternatives that address the  types of
losses with which indemnification may be concerned.  Fart III examines
how alternative mechanisms are presently used to  remedy or prevent
loss situations or to provide incentives under existing environmental
programs.  Part IV suggests a framework for choosing between indemni-
fication and an alternative relief mechanism.
                                 B-2

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix B
                  II.   THE OPERATION OF ALTERNATIVES
     EPA-sponsored indemnification theoretically may operate in two
 ways.   Either payment of indemnification arises after the fact of loss
 resulting from a situation determined  to be indemnifiable,  or the
 offer  of  indemnification arises prior  to any loss and operates as a
 pledge of compensation for harms resulting from defined indemnifiable
 situations.   The former type of indemnification may be an ad hoc
 response  to  an unforeseen or unpredicted harm that is thought, in
 fairness, to require indemnification.   It requires no advance authori-
 zation from  Congress, but can be authorized entirely as a one-time
 response  to  particular circumstances.1
                                  c
     In contrast,  any indemnification program thft is established by
 statute or regulation Is, by definition,  of the second type.  A pro-
 gram may  approximate the first type of  indemnification by providing
 only the  most general description of indemnifiable situations or
 harms.^  However,  its more important effect may be to provide a pledge
 upon which specified parties may rely  in encountering the indemnlfi-
 able situation.   The pledge will affect those parties'  conduct either
 explicitly and intentionally^ or indirectly and diffusely.4

     Alternatives  to  indemnification may also operate, In either of the
 two  ways  described above, to achieve some or all of the same results
 achievable through indemnification.  The  available alternative re-
 sponses to a potential or actual loss  situation may be loosely grouped
 into four categories,  depending on whether they are aimed at:

     •   Eliminating  the harms resulting from otherwise indemnifiable
        situations;

     •   Spreading  or shifting such harms;

     •   Reducing  the severity of such harms;  or

     •   Improving  the  ability of affected  parties to absorb harms
        generally.

A.   Alternative Means  of Eliminating Harms

     1.  Financial  Assistance

        Many  environmental regulatory programs  Include some element of
financial  assistance  for persons affected  by them.^  Such assistance
may  take  the  form  of  direct  cash payments  — grants and subsidies, for
example — or  they may be less  direct forms  of  assistance,  such as tax
credits.   Both direct  and indirect financial assistance is  given out
to those  who  satisfy  certain qualifying criteria.
                                 B-3

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix B
        Unlike  some  social  welfare  "entitlement"  programs where aid IB
given  to all who qualify, most  financial  assistance  programs in the
environmental field  involve some  further  limitation  beyond the minimum
qualifying criteria.  This  may  take  the  form of a rating system in
which  various applicants are  rank-ordered,^  or it may be no more than
first-come-first-served rationing.   In any form,  such financial
assistance is often  subject to  the  exercise  of a  certain amount of
administrative  discretion in  selecting recipients.  This discretion
may be structured by regulation in  order  to  facilitate identification
of likely recipients in advance of  their  applying for assistance.

        Federal financial assistance is nearly always accompanied  by a
variety of conditions to which  the  recipient must agree.  Often these
conditions limit, in minute detail,  the disposition  of the funds
involved.  Some of the conditions may have very little relationship to
the main objective of the financial  assistance itself, but may be
included to foster other governmental policy goals.8

        Clearly, indemnification is  one form of financial assistance.
However, in several  important ways,  indemnification  differs from other
forms of assistance.  Indemmification is  generally measured by the
magnitude of the harm, while  other  forms  of  financial assistance may
be measured by whatever reasonable  formula has been  adopted.
Moreover, financial assistance  awards typically place the government
in the role of benefactor who may restrict or condition assistance as
seems  reasonable.  Indemnification,  however,  differs from other finan-
cial assistance in that it  places the government  in  the position of
remedying harms that result from certain  indemnifiable situations, and
thus, when such situations  arise, the government  is  unlikely to impose
such restrictions.

    2.  Exceptions and Waivers

        An exception is a statutory  or regulatory provision that
operates to restrict the general applicability of the language of  the
provision.^  The effect of  an exception is to excuse compliance with
the general provision by those  to whom the exception applies.10 A
waiver is an individual determination that a particular party should
be excused from compliance.

        Both exceptions and waivers  can be alternatives to indem-
nification because they can have the effect  of eliminating the harms
associated with application of  a statutory or regulatory provision.
In general, statutory or regulatory  exceptions are provided when it is
possible to define in advance the precise class of parties or situa-
tions  to which a standard should not apply.    In such a case, an
exception operates as an alternative to the  second type of indemnifi-
cation noted above, since it  serves  as a  statement that the harms  of
regulation will not be imposed  in certain defined "exceptional" cir-
cumstances.

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix B
         When such a definition is not possible,  and Che  determination
 of  whether  the  standard  should apply depends upon a balance  of com-
 peting  considerations,  the  waiver mechanism is appropriate*   A waiver
 mechanism established  by statute or regulation may specify,  in general
 terms or in minute detail,  the considerations to be balanced in
 granting or denying the  waiver.^  When waiver considerations are
 stated  very generally,  the  waiver mechanism most closely approximates
 an  alternative  to the  first type of indemnification noted above,  since
 it  can  be an ad hoc response to  an unforeseen harm caused by imposi-
 tion of a regulatory standard.

         The formal grant of a regulatory exception constitutes admi-
 nistrative  rulemaking; the  formal grant of a waiver constitutes
 adjudication.   Both exceptions and waivers may also exist Informally,
 however,  In the exercise of administrative prosecutorial discretion.
 The practical effect of  an  administrative decision not to pursue  a
 particular  class of violators^  or an individual violator is the  same
 as  if a formal  exception or waiver had been granted.

         Exceptions and waivers may be total,  or  they may involve  the
 concept of  tiering.  Tiering is  an administrative mechanism  which
 allows  the  stringency of a  regulation to vary in proportion  to some
 other factors — the degree of hazard,  the impact on the regulated
 community,  etc.^  Thus,  a  provision may except  one class of parties
 from one  regulatory requirement,  but subject  it  instead  to a less
 stringent requirement.^ Similarly, a waiver may excuse compliance
 with a  particular standard  provided that a lower standard is
 met.l'  Clearly,  both exception and waiver mechanisms can be  designed
 with as  many  or as few tiers as  seems appropriate.

    3.   Facilitated  Participation and Review

        Under the Administrative  Procedure Act,  EPA rulemaking activi-
 ties are  generally subject  to the requirement that  affected  parties  be
 given,  at a minimum, notice of proposed regulations and  an opportunity
 to comment  on them.    Similarly,  affected parties  are entitled to
 participate in  agency adjudicatory decisions.^   In a few
 circumstances,  however,  EPA may  take limited  actions without affording
 such participation,  either  because of the immediacy of the problem
 being addressed20 or because the  action constitutes neither  rulemaking
 nor adjudication.  When  this occurs, the risk of producing undesired
harms is, of course, increased since there is no mechanism for
bringing  the possibility of  such  harms  to the attention  of EPA before
 the action  is taken.

        One method of dealing with this increased risk is to provide
 for an  expeditious hearing  on the EPA action  after  it is taken, so
 that it can be  rescinded  or  modified to avoid the harm,  as appropri-
ate, at an early  date.21  Even where a  hearing has  been  held or notice
and comment procedure has been followed,  the  same objective  of expedi-
                                 B-5

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix B
 tlous review,  modification,  rescission or confirmation may be
 desirable in minimizing or eliminating untoward consequences of EPA
 actions.   In such circumstances, facilitated judical review may be
 appropriate.

        Every  final administrative action — except for those com-
 mitted to agency discretion  by law — is subject to judicial
 review.22 Thus,  judicial review is virtually always available as a
 mechanism for  undoing or modifying certain actions in appropriate
 cases. In a few situations,  Congress has chosen to facilitate judi-
 cial review of administrative action.  This is often accomplished by
 designating a  particular district or circuit court (such as those of
 the  District of  Columbia) as  having exclusive jurisdiction over
 challenges to  the agency's action, or by providing the direct judicial
 review is to occur at the Court of Appeals level."  Such expedited
 review is most often regarded as benefiting the affected administra-
 tive agency, either by avoiding a proliferation of judicial eva-
 luations  of its  actions or by permitting the agency to have a quicker
 evaluation of  its actions, less subject to reversal by a higher court.
 However,  in a  few circumstances, expedited judicial review may operate
 as a benefit to  the party affected by EPA action,  by accelerating the
 implementation of modifications to that action.                      *

        Both facilitated participation and expedited review serve as
 alternatives to  indemnification when they operate  to modify or ter-
 minate quickly a course of EPA regulatory action that is Imposing
 harms on  aggrieved parties.   Like exceptions and waivers,  these alter-
 natives operate  to eliminate  such harms by removing the necessity of
 complying with the standard at issue.   The value of facilitated par-
 ticipation and expedited review,  therefore,  is  derived primarily when
 an EPA action  is ultimately modified,  rescinded  or overturned.

 B.   Alternative  Means  of Spreading or  Shifting Harms

     1.  Restoration Funds

        A restoration  fund is  a sum of money set aside to  pay compen-
 sation under specified  circumstances.   Moneys  for  the fund are  nor-
mally  collected  by  means of an "injury tax"  or  surcharge on a product
or activity related to  the purpose of  the  fund.  Thus,  for example,
Superfund  is a restoration fund financed  (in part) from a  tax imposed
on crude  oil received at  a United States refinery,  imported petroleum
products,   crude  oil exports and uses,2* and  42 specific chemical
products.2^

        A restoration fund differs from indemnification, although both
involve payments measured  by certain defined harms,  in that the amount
of the  fund is collected  in advance  in anticipation of  the necessity
of payouts. The  fund is kept separate  from other revenues  and may con-
tinue  to  grow  year  after year until  payouts  are  necessary.
                                 B-6

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix B
 Eligibility  for  compensation  from the  fund may be limited by the total
 anount  available^  at  the  time  of the  discovery of the loss, or it may
 be  measured  only by the  indemnification formula established.    The
 levels  of  the  injury  tax may  theoretically be made to vary in propor-
 tion  to the  fund's  payout  experience.   In contrast, indemnification is
 normally financed from general  revenues and its amount is measured
 only  by the  indemnification formula  established.

         Payments from  a  restoration  fund are typically conditioned on
 a triggering event.^8  Such events must  be statistically foreseeable,
 even  if they are not actually predictable, and their probability may
 vary  with  an activity  upon which  the tax or surcharge can be levied.

         The  existence  of a restoration  fund in the first Instance
 clearly obviates the need  to  provide indemnification, and thus serves
 as  an alternative to indemnification.   Restoration funds do not shift
 the costs  of harms  to  EPA, however,  as  indemnification would,  but
 rather  distribute those  costs among  those contributing to the fund.
 Requiring  payments  into  a  restoration fund In anticipation of a trig-
 gering  event such as might be the subject of indemnification thus for-
 ces industry members to  share the risks involved in their enterprises.
 Restoration  funds are  therefore essentially mechanisms for spreading
 the risks  of certain activities among all those engaged in the acti-
 vity, rather than letting  the untoward  consequences of those activi-
 ties  fall  on an  unlucky  few, or on the  government agency providing
 indemnification.

    2.   Limitation  of  Liability

        A  limitation of  liability is a  statutory declaration that a
 party whose  conduct or product causes harms will not be held.account-
 able  for all of  those  harms.29  A limitation of liability is an alter-
 native  to  indemnification when the harms being addressed would
 initially  fall on a diffuse group of parties who, in the absence of
 such a  limitation, would claim compensation from the responsible party
who,  in turn, would be in  need of indemnification from the government.
Like Indemnification,  a  limitation of liability shifts the relevant
 risk away  from the  party engaged  in  the activity or producing the pro-
duct  creating the risk.  Thus, like  indemnification, a limitation of
liability  removes an economic impediment to a particular activity or
product  in order  to stimulate those  who would otherwise be willing to
engage  in  the activity or develop the product.^  However, unlike
indemnification,  the limitation of liability shifts that risk to those
who Initially suffer the harm,31  rather than to a government body pro-
viding  indemnification.

        A limitation of  liability may be a feasible alternative to
indemnification when it  operates  to  shift harms to a group who are
readily able to  absorb them, and  to  spread those harms among members
of that group.   Since  this shift  occurs without significant transac-
                                 B-7

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix B
 tion  costs,  it  can prove to be a relatively trouble-free alternative.
 Indeed,  a  limitation of  liability will nearly always  be an alternative
 of  lower cost  than indemnification In situations to which it can be
 made  to  apply•

 C.  Alternative Means of Reducing the Severity of Harms

    1.   Postponement of  Compliance Deadlines

         A  postponement of compliance  deadlines occurs when compliance
 is  excused for  a  period  of time after a statutory or  administrative
 regulatory action is taken.3^   Such postponements are quite common,
 and are  usually conceived of as necessary in order to give notice to
 the affected parties that the  regulatory action has occurred,  and an
 opportunity  for such parties to adjust their activities in response in
 an  orderly fashion within a reasonable time.

         Many regulatory  actions are taken with a general postponement
 of  their effective date  accompanying  them.   Thus, for example, a regu-
 latory standard may be promulgated with an effective  date a specified
 length of  time  after its Federal Register publication.33  Alter-
 natively,  the regulation itself may state that the affected activity
 must comport to the regulatory standard by a specific future date.3*

         In theory,  if not often in practice, postponements may be made
 applicable to some classes of  regulated parties,  and  not to others.
 More common are policies,  adopted either by regulation or otherwise,
 not to require  compliance with a regulatory standard  by all those
 against  whom enforcement is regarded  as not immediately appropriate,
 for example, because of  their  difficulty or expense in complying.36 A
 formal grant of a postponement in such circumstances  constitutes an
 administrative  adjudication.   However,  a less formal  postponement may
 be  regarded as  a  mere exercise of prosecutorial discretion.

        As a practical matter,  postponements are  also often bargained
 for in the course of prosecution and  defense of enforcement
 actions.3^  Thus,  even when a  decision is made to prosecute such an
 action,  the key objective  of enforcement — compliance with the stan-
dard — may be  achieved  (and more quickly)  by means of a settlement
 including  a legally enforceable compliance  deadline,  rather than by
protracted litigation.

        Postponements  may  be regarded as alternatives to indem-
nification to the extent that  they will reduce the severity of harms
associated with a regulatory activity.   In  some circumstances, post-
ponements merely  delay those harms and  arguably do not reduce  their
 severity.  However,  where  compliance  is facilitated or made more
orderly  by a postponement,  harms  may  be made less severe without the
need for indemnification.
                                 B-8

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix  B
     2.   Forebearance with Publicity

         There  are  a number  of ways available  to  EPA  to  achieve  some  or
all  of  its  regulatory goals without actually  engaging in  rulemaking  or
adjudication.38  One such way is  to act merely  to  publicize  the fact
or action that might otherwise be the  subject of regulatory
concern.39  Rather than  to  prohibit the action,  or ban  the product  in
question, EPA may  simply inform merchants,  retailers and  the public  of
the  possible environmental  risks at issue.

         Such an action would not constitute rulemaking, would not com-
pel  any  particular response from the affected parties and would not  be
subject  to  judicial review.  The affected party  is left free to
behave,  in  response to the  publicity,  in whatever  manner  it  deems
appropriate.  By publicizing that behavior, however, EPA may stimulate
market or other forces to induce proper behavior.  In an  appropriate
case, the primary objective will be achieved  in  either event, but if
EPA  has  done no more than publicize the party's  activity, it will have
done nothing that, in fairness, can be the basis for indemnification.
Indeed,  the total harm to the affected party  will  likely  be  less,
since it will be left free  to devise its own  solution to  the environ-
mental problem at hand.

         Foregoing regulatory action in favor  of  an alternative  such  as
publicity operates as an alternative to indemnification in the  sense
that it  reduces the adverse consequences of regulatory activity.  This
reduction may be achieved at some cost in the health or environmental
benefit  to  the public, but  it allows regulated parties to design their
own  response to the problem, in proportion to market incentives or
threats  of  liability.

D.  Alternative Means of Improving Ability to Absorb Harms

    1.  Education and Information Transfer

        One important function of regulatory  agencies, closely  related
to forebearance with publicity, is to educate those  affected by their
actions and to provide information to the regulated  community and the
public concerning the need for agency action, the  risk being
addressed,  the rationale for the regulatory strategy followed and the
means of complying with, or otherwise accommodating, the agency
action.^0  Such education and information transfer serve as  an  alter-
native to Indemnification by improving the ability of affected  parties
to absorb harms they have incurred.

        Effective educational and information programs can reduce
resistance  to regulatory activity; produce a  cooperative  relationship
between  the agency and the regulated community;  improve the  quality  of
participation in a regulatory program by the  regulated community and
the public, and lower the overall costs Imposed  by regulatory action.
                                 B-9

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix B
Thus,  they  can  be  an  important  alternative to indemnification.   When
the harms arising  out  of  regulatory  action can be  reduced  signifi-
cantly  through  educational  efforts by  the agency (for  example,  on the
lowest  cost method of  meeting a new  regulatory standard),  the need  for
indemnification is correspondingly reduced.   If educational efforts
can reduce  the  adverse impacts  of EPA  action to a  level reasonably
absorbed by affected parties, no indemnification will  be required at
all.

    2.  Resource and Technology Pooling

        Resource and  technology pooling consists of  joint  efforts
among one or more  federal agencies,  other levels of  government  or pri-
vate firms  to share technological Innovations, research and develop-
ment, economic  or  other resources in order to reduce the costs
associated  with regulatory  action and  to foster innovation.^1 Resource
pooling occurs  when funds or capital resources are contributed  to a
single venture  or  activity  addressed to a common regulatory impact.
Technology  pooling occurs when  specific equipment  or technology is
shared with others who are  engaged in  parallel activity in response to
regulatory  action.

        Resource and technology pooling can  occur  without  any gov-
ernment involvement at all  — at least in those circumstances where
antitrust laws  do  not  interfere.  However,  there is  much that the fed-
eral government can do to participate  in such pooling  or to encourage
participation by others.  For example,  EPA might pursue a  policy of
liberalized licensure  of patents held  by the government for those par-
ticipating  in resource or technology pools.   Similarly the Agency
could tie other benefits to such participation.

        Resource and technology pooling is obviously a means of
improving the ability  of affected parties to absorb  the harms asso-
ciated with regulatory activity, and thus can be regarded  as an alter-
native to indemnification in this sense.  When pooling results  in
lower individual costs being incurred  in response  to administrative
action — for example,  when technology is shared to  take advantage  of
economies of scale —  the desired objective  is achieved without indem-
nification  and  resistance to the action may  be reduced. This,  for
example, appears to be the  purpose of  the pooling  of data  and study
results under TSCA.^2

        However, creation of a  pool  does  not,  by itself, always
guarantee amelioration.  For example,  where  administrative action is
designed to force  technology, a resource  pool designed to  undertake
research and development may achieve the  necessary breakthrough,  but
it may also fail.
                                 B-10

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Appendix  B
    3.  Partial Financial Assistance

        Financial assistance may provide something  less  than  full  cash
payment te- its recipient.  Thus, once it ia determined that a par-
ticular sum is required, that sum may be loaned, rather  than  paid, or
an Interest subsidy or repayment insurance^ may be written to  facili-
tate private funding, or a smaller amount may be paid.44

        Although partial financial assistance is generally a  mechanism
for Improving the ability of assisted parties to absorb  the impact of
regulatory activity, rather than to eliminate those harms as  would
full cash assistance, they are structurally otherwise identical.
                                 B-ll

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix B
            III.   LEGISLATIVE TREATMENT OF LOSS SITUATIONS
    When the  various  statutes  administered by EPA are examined in
 relation to the  possible  loss  situations that can arise under them,
 the most striking conclusion is the consistency with which the various
 situations have  been  treated by Congress across the range of environ-
 mental  legislation.   A strong  pattern emerges, reflecting a congres-
 sional  routine — whether it amounts to a congressional preference  is
 unclear — for avoiding or responding to these situations.  With a  few
 exceptions, congressional consistency appears to be far greater than
 one might have expected from a political forum.

    Clearly Congress  has  often acted more to avoid loss situations
 than  to create a remedy for them.   Repeatedly, Congress has demon-
 strated its willingness to compromise primary statutory objectives
 rather  than face the  likelihood of  creating loss situations requiring
 indemnification.   This suggests a congressional willingness to assign
 even  important legislative objectives relatively less weight than loss
 situation avoidance.   To  the extent that this desire can be translated
 into  a  congressional  policy, the implication to be drawn is that
 indemnification  ought not to be rejected in a particular case merely
 because a legislatively mandated program objective would be compro-
 mised by payment.  Rather,  congressional policy seems to be that the
 harms suggested  in the indemnification situations are usually of
 greater concern  than  the  objectives of the statutory scheme.

    On  the other  hand,  it is also clear that indemnification is not  a
 favored response  to loss  situations.   Rather,  other measures are
 nearly  always provided most of  them designed to avoid the situations
 entirely.  Thus,  a second congressional policy to be derived from this
 analysis is that  indemnification should be regarded as a strategy of
 last  resort, to  be pursued  only when no acceptable alternative appears
 and compromise of  the legislative objective is impossible.

A.  Emergency Powers

    This situation involves EPA emergency actions which prove to be
 ill-conceived but  which are excluded  from the Federal Tort Claims
Act'*5 because they arise  out of the exercise of EPA discretion.
Although, in emergency  situations,  EPA can make errors of judgment in
promulgating regulations,  formulating policy,  or taking remedial
action,  Congress has  never  formally addressed such errors in its
legislation.

    Where EPA error is  not  the  basis  for indemnification, the exercise
of emergency powers has given  rise  to the mandate for indemnification
in only  one instance.  This mandate appears in § 15 of the Federal
Insecticide, Fungicide and  Rodenticide Act (FIFRA).46  No other
                                 B-12

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix B
 suggestion appears in any other environmental statute,  however,  that
 the threat of emergency action should give rise to the  need  to provide
 indemnification.

 B.   Change of Regulatory Policy

     A  loss situation may occur whenever new information or under-
 standing  produces  a change in EPA's regulatory program.  Such a  change
 may be most abrupt when EPA reverses a prior position generally
 approving or even  positively sanctioning a particular product or
 activity.  However,  the loss situation may also arise after  EPA
 acquiescence or complete nonaction with respect to a product or
 activity.
                                     o
     The usual response  to the policy change situation is to  grant a
 temporary variance from,  or postpone the deadline  for compliance with,
 the newly necessitated  regulatory  requirement.^?  In some instances,
 the effectiveness  of any new requirement is explicitly  delayed for a
 period of time.  In  others, its application to those who seem to nave
 the greatest stake in the prior state of affairs is delayed.^8  in
 still  others,  elaborate safeguards are included before  changes can be
 made — thus eliminating the possibility of suddenness.*'

     These treatments of the policy change situation reflect  congres-
 sional willingness,  noted above, to compromise the primary objectives
 of  EPA's  programs,  rather than to  disrupt affected activities with
 policy or regulatory changes.   This willingness may perhaps  be
 explained by the realization that  environmental regulation continues
 to  be  an  inexact process,  involving some measure of guess work as well
 as  hard data and analysis.   Where  technical uncertainty is acknowl-
 edged, it is obviously  most difficult to insist on regulatory action
 as  if  such uncertainty  were eliminated.   Rather, it may be justifiable
 to  seek to  minimize  disruption when such uncertainty causes  sudden
 changes in EPA's regulatory program.

    On the  other hand,  detrimental reliance by an  affected party on a
 regulatory  policy  or  provision, which,  when rescinded causes that
 party  to  and suffer  a harm  is  often cited as an Important regulatory
 relief concern.  None of  the environmental statutes explicitly deals
with the  detrimental  reliance  situation.

C.  Tort  Situations Potentially Not Covered Under  the Federal
    Tort  Claims Act;  Delays and Ineffective EPA Action;
    Unreasonable Enforcement;  and  Disclosure of Confidential
    Business Information

    These  situations  occur  whenever EPA commits a  tortious act that is
not  compensable under the Federal  Tort  Claims Act.50 Although there
are many  conceivable  tortious  acts that  EPA could  conceivably commit,
the  three  cited are most  often mentioned.
                                 B-13

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix B
     The  problem  of  unreasonable  enforcement  is  considered,  but  only
 once,  In the  various enviornmental  statutes.  Section 113(b)  of the
 Clean  Air Act,^ which  deals with enforcement actions by  the  Adminis-
 trator of EPA, authorizes  the award of  litigation  costs  to  a  party
 against  whom  an unreasonable action was brought.   No .obvious  explana-
 tion appears  for the existence of this  particular  provision,  limited
 to  air enforcement  actions, when no similar  provisions exist  under
 other  environmental statutes.  In general, however, the Clean Air Act
 is  the most complex of  the environmental statutes  and the one which
 underwent perhaps the most extensive revision after Its initial
 enactment.  Regulatory  relief provisions are thus  more common in the
 Clean  Air Act than  in the other  environmental statutes, and this
 political and historical reason  may account  for the existence of this
 provision.

     Other tortious  EPA  conduct is ignored throughout  the  various
 statutes*

 D.   Conflicting Requirements

    This  situation  occurs when a federal environmental regulation or
 statute mandates or effectively  compels conduct that  is prohibited by
 another  state or federal provision.  It also occurs when  a  federal
 environmental provision prohibits an activity that is  mandated  or
 effectively compelled by another federal or state  program.

    The conflicting requirements situation rarely  occurs  in practice.
There  is  an ample body  of rules  governing conflicts of law  designed to
assure that such situations will not arise.52   Nevertheless,  various
 state  and federal enactments do  have differing  (and arguably
conflicting)  objectives, and these  conflicts do need  to be  resolved.

    The various envionmental statutes contain many provisions for
avoiding  the  conflicting requirements situation but not for remedying
it.  These avoidance mechanisms  consist of either  (1)  rules for
assigning primary responsibility to  one regulatory regime when  a
conflict  appears;^^ and (2) requirements that regulatory  actions be
coordinated.5*

E.  The Incentive Situation

    This  situation occurs when EPA wishes to provide an incentive for
an activity or conduct  involving risk,  which the party to whom  the
incentive is provided would not undertake because  of  that risk.   The
situation seems most likely to arise where a new technology is  desired
to be encouraged, but any desired activity involving risk may give
rise to this  situation.

    The "classic" example of this situation la  represented  by
§ 202(a)(3) of the Clean Water Act.55   That section provides  for
                                 B-U

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix B
 indemnification for the cost of constructing innovative and alter-
 native wastewater treatment facilities that later fail to perform as
 expected.  Clearly this section is designed to encourage investment in
 such facilities by reducing the fear of failing to meet performance
 specifications.

     The environmental statutes are replete with provisions designed to
 encourage particular types of conduct.  Few, however, provide that
 incentive by means of risk absorption, despite the high degree of
 technical uncertainty in environmental regulation and the various
 technology forcing policies reflected in the statutes.

     Section 1441 of the Safe Drinking Water Act,56 offers an example
 of an incentive situation.  In an earlier paragraph of that section,
 Congress provided for a certification of need to be issued to any per-
 son who uses chlorine or other chemicals f'or treating public water
 supplies and who determines that the amount of such chemicals reason-
 ably available to him will be inadequate to treat that water
 effectively.  When the certification Is Issued, it is accompanied by
 an order to an appropriate manufacturer, producer or processor,
 directing sale of the needed chemicals to the certified treatment
 facility.

     Paragraph (d) then provides:

               There shall be available as a defense to any
               action brought for breach of contract in a
               Federal or State court arising out of delay or
               failure to provide,  sell or offer for sale or
               exchange a chemical  or substance subject to an
               order issued pursuant  to subsection (c)(l),
               that such delay or failure was caused solely
               by compliance with such order.

 Thus,  this  section authorizes EPA  to eliminate one of the risks of
 drinking water treatment — loss of  chemical supplies — by a certifi-
cation  procedure designed to guarantee the supply.  In this situation,
 the  desire  to guarantee a continuous flow of safe drinking water makes
 indemnification an unsuitable device for risk absorption, and supply
 guarantees  a preferred strategy.
                                 B-15

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Appendix B
        IV.  A FRAMEWORK FOR CHOOSING BETWEEN INDEMNIFICATION
                  AND ALTERNATIVE RELIEF MECHANISM
    The choice between indemnification and an alternative relief
mechanism depends largely on the circumstances of the particular loss
situation involved or the nature of the incentive desired.  For any
particular situation defined, the choice depends on the answer to two
questions

    •   Will an Alternative Produce a Remedial Result Comparable to
        Indemnification?

    •   How Vill Use of the Alternative Affect Program Objectives?

Table I illustrates how the answers to these two questions assists in
the selection between indemnification and an alternative.
                                B-16

-------
                      WILL AN ALTERNATIVE PRODUCE A REMEDIAL RESULT COMPARABLE TO INDEMNIFICATION?

How will use of
an alternative
affect program
objectives?

Beneficial
No or Neutral
Effect
Adverse Effect
No Worse Than
Indemnification
Adverse Effect
Not Unacceptably
Worse Than
Indemnification
Adverse Effect
Unacceptably
Worse Than
Indemnification
Yes At Least at
Effective as
Indemnification
A
A
A
A
B
Not as
Enough to
Obviate Need for
Indemnification
B
B
B
B
E
Effective as Indemn
Enough to
Narrow Range of
Indemnification
Situation
C
C
C
D
E
if Icatlon
Indemnification
Still Needed
E
E
E
E
E
I
»"—•
^J
     A • reject indemnification;  choose alternative (threshold analysis)
     B • consider alternative as  factor in deciding whether to Indemnify (balancing analysis)
     C • choose alternative;  redefine indemnification situation more narrowly;  repeat Step 1 (Iterative analysis)
     D « consider whether to  choose alternative and redefine indemnification situation more narrowly; repeat Step 1
         (balancing and iterative analysis)
     E - reject alternative;  other factors determine whether to 4"demnlfy

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix B
                        FOOTNOTES  TO  APPENDIX B

     1If  passed,  the Trls  Indemnification Bill,  S.  823  (97th Cong.,
 1st  Seas.) would be an example of post-hoc authorization of indemnifi-
 cation.   See  "Payments of Losses  incurred as a  Result  of the Ban  on
 the  Use  of the Chemical Tris," Report  of the Committee on the Judici-
 ary, U.S. Senate,  97th Cong.,  1st Seas.  (1981).

     2Section  113(b) of the Clean  Air Act,  42 U.S.C.  S  7413,  is argu-
 ably the least specific of the existing  indemnification provisions in
 environmental statutes.   While it defines  indemnif iable harms with
 some precision ("costs of litigation"),  its definition of the indem-
 nifiable situation ("unreasonable" enforcement  action) is fairly  open
 to interpretation.

     3Section  202(a)(3) of the  Clean  Water  Act.  33  U.S.C.  S  1282(a)(3),
 offers such an explicit and intentional  incentive  for  constructing
 innovative and alternative waatewater  treatment  facilities.

     ^It  has been suggested, for example,  that §  IS of  the Federal
 Insecticide,  Fungicide and Rodenticide Act (PIFRA),  7  U.S.C.  §  126m,
 provides an indirect incentive for pesticide manufacturers  not  to   |
 engage in certain  research and development activities,  but  rather to
 rely on  the pesticide  registration process,  because  indemnification
will be  available  if EPA  determines  that marketing and use  of  the
pesticide must end  before stocks  are depleted.
         Construction Grants Program under the Clean Water Act, 33
U.S.C. §§ 1281-1297, for example, is generally regarded as a means of
overcoming the burden imposed on local governments by the Act's
requirement of secondary treatment of municipal effluent.  33 U.S.C.
§ 1311(b)(l)(B).

    "Construction grant funds, for example are allocated according to
a formula set forth in 33 U.S.C. S 1285.  As described by one
observer:

              This program provides grants to states based
              on (a) severity of problems, (b) existing
              population affected, and (c) need for preser-
              vation of high quality waters. . . .During FY.
              1976 $4.9 billion were obligated for this pro-
              gram.  The data elements used in this program
              are state population estimates for July 1975,
              published by the Bureau of the Census, and
              various components of need determined by a
              survey to estimate cost of construction of
              publicly owned wastewater facilities.  In
              determining these needs, the projected popula-
              tion for 1990, prepared by the Bureau of
                                 B-18

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Appendix B
              Economic Analysis  (BEA) and  based on Census
              Series 1-E,  is  compared with  the population
              for July 1975.  This  program  includes both a
              House formula and  a Senate formula.  The House
              formula is additive with  three components:
              (a) a needs  factor that includes costs for
              secondary treatment plants, weighted double
              .  . . ; (b)  a needs factor that includes
              rehabilitation  of  sewers  and  control of sewer
              overflow . . .  ; (c)  and  state population for
              July 1975.   Each factor is a  ratio of the
              state estimate  to  the sum for all states.  The
              Senate formula  chooses the larger of the state
              population ration and the ratio of a third set
              of needs estimates for the state. . . .These
              initial entitlement estimates are prorated so
              that they sum to 100 percent.  The next step
              is to check  that the Senate percentage for
              each state is at least .5 percent.  This pro-
              cess is repeated until the sum of the state
              percentages  based on  the  Senate formula equals
              100 percent.  After both  the House and Senate
              formulas have been computed,  the compromise
              state entitlement percentage is obtained by
              weighting the two estimates equally.

Gonzalez, "Characteristics of Formulas  and Data Used in the Allocation
of Federal Funds, 34 American Statistician 200. 207-08 (1980).

    'See Gilhooley, "Standards and Procedures for the Discretionary
Distribution of Federal Assistance," in Administrative Conference of
the United States, 3 Recommendations and Reports 422 (1974).

    8 Some of these are enumerated In Cappalli, "Mandates Attached to
Federal Grants:  Sweet and Sour Federalism," 13 Urban Law. 143 (1981).

    9Jensen v. Garrison. 241 F. Supp. 523 (D. Ore. 1965); Sands,
Sutherland's Statutory Construction § 47.11.
           statutory provisions except activities from regulation when
it would be nonsensical to compel compliance.  For example, the Noise
Control Act prohibits removal of noise abatement devices from
products, 42 U.S.C. § 4909(a)(2), but except s from the prohibition the
removal of such devices for repair purposes.  Id.  Other exceptions
appear when the cost of compliance appears not to be justified in
light of the expense.  TSCA's exception from requirements to submit
reports and data that EPA already has is an example.  15 U.S.C.
§ 2607(a)(2).

    11See. e.g., 33 U.S.C. 5 1342(e), authorizing a waiver of the
requirement that states notify EPA of every permit application
                                 B-19;

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix B
 received  under  the National  Pollution  Discharge Elimination  System
 (NPDES) and of  every action  related  to the consideration of  such
 permits.

    *2Thus, for example,  the Clean Air Act exempts certain non-profit
 health or education facilities  from  "prevention of significant
 deterioration"  (PSD) review.  42 U.S.C.  § 7479(1).
           e*8- > the Clean Air Act's  provision  for waiver of the con-
tinuous emissions reduction  technology  requirement for primary non-
ferrous smelters where  the requirement  is  found to be likely to cause
a cessation of  operations.   42 U.S.C. § 7419(d)(2).

    l^An example of such a decision occurred when EPA announced that
it would not enforce the 1980 annual  report requirement for hazardous
waste generators and owners  and operators  of hazardous waste treatment
and disposal facilities.  46 Fed. Reg.  8395 (January 26, 1981).  The
requirement has since been suspended.
        key criticism of EPA's regulatory program under the Resource
Conservation and Recovery Act (RCRA), 42 U.S.C. §§ 6901 et seq.. for
example, has been its failure to incorporate tiered exemptions based
on the degree of hazard of each particular waste.  Compare Cal. Health
& Safety Code § 25115 (defining "extremely hazardous waste").  See
Chemical Manufacturers Association, A System for Management of
Hazardous Wastes by Degree of Hazard under Subtitle C of RCRA
(updated) .

    1 ^ RCRA, for example, excludes from solid waste regulation those
discharges that are already regulated under the arguably less
stringent Clean Water Act. 42 U.S.C. § 6903(27).

    17For example, § 301 (c) of the Clean Water Act, 33 U.S.C.
§ 1311(c) authorizes EPA to excuse point sources from meeting effluent
limitations based on "best available technology economically achiev-
able" (BAT) if they achieve "maximum use of technology within the eco-
nomic capability of the owner or operator."

    185 U.S.C. § 553.

    195 U.S.C. § 554.

    2°The Toxic Substances Control Act (TSCA), for example, permits
certain types of rules to be effective immediately upon their
proposal.  15 U.S.C. § 2605.

    2*In the TSCA provision noted supra note 20, for example, such an
expeditious hearing is provided.  15 U.S.C. § 2065(d).

    225 U.S.C. §§ 551, 702.
                                 B-20

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix B
             for example,  provides  for judicial  review of  most  regula-
 tions issued under the  Act  in the  District  of Columbia Circuit Court
 of Appeals.  15 U.S.C §  26i8(a).

     Judicial review may,  as  a practical  matter,  be  facilitated in
 other ways as well.  For  example,  an  agency can  facilitate  review of a
 praticular activity by  designating it as final agency action and  thus
 removing any question of  its ripeness for review.   Another  example
 occurs when an agency's governing  statute sets a review standard  for
 agency action that is more precise or better defined  than the
 "arbitrary and capricious" and  "substantial evidence" standards of the
 APA.

     24Internal Revenue Code.  26 U.S.C. § 4611.

     25Internal Revenue Code,  26 U.S.C. § A661.
             the Comprehensive Environmental Response, Compensation  and
Liability Act  (CERCLA),  the Hazardous response Trust Fund  is  to  be      v,
funded  from  the tax  revenues noted supra notes 24, 25, as  well as by
direct  appropriations of $44 million per year.  42 U.S.C.  § 9631(b)(2).

    27See, e.g.. 42  U.S.C. § 9631(c)(2).

    28Cf. 42 U.S.C.  § 9631(c)(l)i

    29See. e.g.. 42  U.S.C. § 9611(a).
        limitation of liability provision appears in § 141(d) of  the
Safe Drinking Water Act, 42 U.S.C § 300j(d), but this provision was
allowed to expire on September 30, 1979.

    3*In Duke Power Co. v. Carolina Environmental Study Group. Inc.,
438 U.S. 59  (1978), the U.S. Supreme Court characterized liability
limitation as "a classic example of an economic regulation—a legisla-
tive effort  to structure and accommodate 'the burdens and benefits of
'economic life.'"  438 U.S. at 83, quoting Usery v. Turner Elkhorn
Mining Co..  428 U.S. 1, 15 (1976).

    32Forcing such parties to absorb such harms, however, is unlikely
to amount to a sufficient ground for declaring the limitation of
liability unconstitutional.  See id., Duke Power Co.

    33Sands, supra note 9, at § 20.24.
    34
      See,
the Noise Control Act's provisions postponing compli-
ance with product noice emission standards until six months after pro-
posed standards are published in order to facilitate orderly design
modifications.  42 U.S.C. § 4905(b).
                                 B-21

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix  B
    35The Clean Water Act's effluent  limitation  provisions, 33 U.S.C.
§  1311,  for example, specify a timetable  for achieving best prac-
ticable  control technology (BPT), generally by July  1, 1977, and best
conventional pollutant control technology (BCT)  generally by July 1,
1984.  33 U.S.C. §§ 1311(b)(l)(A), 1311(b)(2)(E).

    36see, e.g. , 42 U.S.C. § 7419, which  authorizes  primary nonferrous
smelter  orders postponing application of  State Implementation Plan
(SIP) requirements to such smelters if  they are  unable to comply by
the applicable date because no means  of emission limitation is avail-
able.

    37Compare § 301(c) of the Clean Water Act. 33 U.S.C. § 1311(c),
with § 119 of the Clean Air Act. 42 U.S.C. S 7419.

    38See, e.g., United States v. Homes take Mining Co., 26 Fed. Rules
Serv. 2d 194 (D.S.D. 1978); 33 U.S.C. § 1319(a)(5)(B).
          existence of formats of agency action other than ruleraaklng
and adjudication was recognized by the U.S. Supreme Court in I.T.T.
Corp. v. Electrical Workers Local 134. 419 U.S. 600 (1975).  In that
case a labor union appealed an order of the National Labor Relations f
Board based on a finding that the union had committed an unfair labor
practice.  The appeal cited an alleged violation of § 5 of the APA, 5
U.S.C. § 554, and argued that under the section It was improper for
the same Individual to act first as a hearing officer at the hearing
concerning the charges held pursuant to § 10(k) of the National Labor
Relations Act, 29 U.S.C. § 10(k) , and then later to prosecute the
unfair labor practice charge.

    The Court held that the § 10(k) determination was only a prelimi-
nary administrative determination to resolve a dispute, and therefore
was not within the scope of § 5:

              If one were to start with the proposition that
              all administrative action falls into one of
              two categories, rulemaking or adjudication,
              the Section 10(k) determination certainly is
              closer to the latter than to the former.  But
              such light as we have on the intention of
              Congress when it enacted the Act does not
              Indicate that this Is a sound starting point.
              Knowledgeable authorities in this field
              observed shortly after the passage of the Act
              that "certain types of agency action are
              neither rulemaking nor adjudication."  Ginane,
              "Rule Making" "Adjudication" and "Exemptions
              Under the Administrative Procedure Act, 95
              U. Pa. L.Rev. 621 633, (1947); Netterville,
              The Administrative Procedure Act:  A Study in
                                 B-22

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Appendix  B
               Interpretation,  20  Geo. Wash.  L. Rev.  1, 33
               (1951);  Cf.  Attorney  General's Manual  on the                              •
               Administrative Procedure  Act 40  (1947).  ..."                            i
                                                                                        I
    The Ginane article cites,  as  an example  of the point rade,  the                      j
 investigation  of  aircraft  accidents by  the Civil Aeronautics Board*
 Such  an investigation  results  in  findings as to the  accident's  cause
 and also  in  recommendations for operational  changes, if necessary.  It
 does  not  result in  the issuance of  an order  (ad juciation) , or of an
 agency statement  proscribing further conduct (rulemaking).

                  National  Ornament  & Electric Light  Christmas Ase'n v.
 CPSC, 526 F.2d 1368  (1975).  Professor  Ernest Gellhorn in "Adverse
 Publicity by Administrative Agencies,"  86 Harv. L. Rev. 1380 (1973)
 (based upon  report prepared for the Administrative Conference of the
 United States), examines the lack of standards for issuing such publi-
 city  and  proposes reforms  intended  to better control the use of
 adverse publicity.
          various environmental statutes are replete with provisions
of  this  type.  See, e.g., the Noise Control Act. 42 U.S.C. § 4904(b),
requiring publication of reports on major sources of noise and on
techniques for noise control, in order to facilitate compliance with
noise emission standards.

               ., JRB Associates, Inc., Checklist Papers of Alter-
natives  and Supplements to Direct Regulation for Environmental
Protection. 26-1 (EPA Contract No. 68.01.4991)(1980).

    4315 U.S.C. § 2604(b)(2)(B).
      See, e.g., 33 U.S.C.  § 1293, providing loan guarantees for
POTWs where credit is otherwise unavailable.

    A5See, e.g.. 33 U.S.C. § 1282(a)(l), providing for EPA to assume
a portion of the cost of construction of POTWs.
         U.S.C. § 2680(a)  [FTCA discretionary function exception] .

    477 U.S.C. § 136m.

    A8See, e.g.. Clean Air Act. 42 U.S.C. §§ 7413(d)(8) (delaying
termination of postponement orders to avoid undue hardship); 7419 (e)
(delaying termination of primary nonferrous smelter orders until no
undue hardship would result).

    49See. e.g.. Clean Water Act. 42 U.S.C. §§ I316(d) (protecting
complying point sources from new performance standards for ten years);
1326(c) (providing similar protection from thermal discharge limita-
tions) .
                                 B-23

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Appendix B
    50S_ee_, e.g., FIFRA, 7 U.S.C. § 136d.  Other provided responses
include:

      (a)  TSCA

           15 U.S.C. § 2605(d):    expeditious hearing on immediately
                                   effective proposed rules.

      (b)  Clean Air Act

           42 U.S.C. § 7525(b):    expedited Judicial review of
                                   suspension or revocation of motor
                                   vehicle emission certifications.

           42 U.S.C. § 7525(g):    nonconformance penalty option in
                                   lieu of suspension or revocation of
                                   heavy duty vehicle emission
                                   certification.

    S^The exceptions to the FTCA waiver of sovereign immunity are con-
tained in 28 U.S.C. S 2680.

    5242 U.S.C. § 7413.

          generally Sands,  Sutherland's Statutory Construction.

          example:

      (a)  TSCA

           15 U.S.C. § 2602(b):    excludes from TSCA those substances
                                   regulated under FIFRA, the Atomic
                                   Energy Act, FDA and other statutes.

           15 U.S.C. S 2608(a):    assigns primacy to all statutes not
                                   administered by EPA.

           15 U.S.C. § 2617:        preemption of state law.

      (b)  Safe Drinking Water Act

           33 U.S.C. § 300q-3:      authorizes state regulation of safe
                                   drinking water.
      (c)  Clean Water Act

           33 U.S.C.  S 1370:
authorizes state clean water
regulations.
                                 B-24

-------
(d)  Noise Control Act

     42 U.S.C..S 4905(c):




 (e)  RCRA

      42 U.S^.5 6905(b):


      42 U.S.C.. § 6963:


  (f)  r.Tean Air Act

      42  U.S.C.  §  7402:


5633 U.S.C. § I282(a)(e).
                                      TimcMMT FT CATION STUD1
                                      Appendix B
requires consideration of other
federal regulatory standards before
promulgation of products standards.
 provides  for  integration with  other
 environmental statutes.

 requires  all  federal agencies
 cooperate with EPA.
to
 encourages cooperative state acti-
 vities and uniform laws.
                                B-26

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Appendix C
                             APPENDIX C
                     CONSULTATION WITH INDUSTRY
                                                                 Page

I.     Introduction	C-2

II.    Industry Contacts	C-3

III.   Example Letter	C-A
                                 C-l

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix C
                           I.   INTRODUCTION
     During  the  final  phase  of  the  study,  representatives of industry
were contacted to obtain  more information  relating  to  specific circum-
stances warranting  indemnification  and  the general  reaction of
industry to  the  indemnification option.

     In order to reach persons  who  might be familiar with EPA regula-
tory problems on an industry-wide basis, trade  associations were the
primary target for  consultation.  Over  10  trade associations repre-
senting industries  likely to have environmental concerns  were
contacted; in most  cases,  telephone discussions with several people
within each  association were conducted.

     Many persons contacted  were unfamiliar with the concept of
indemnification.  Frequently, persons requested a written description
of the study and of  information that might be provided.   In response
to this type of  request,  nine letters were sent to  trade  associations
(see attachment).   Most persons who requested that  letter be sent  to
them indicated their intention  to distribute copies of the letter
among trade  association members or  to circulate the letter among the
professional staff.  Therefore,  it  is likely that a much  larger, but
indeterminate, number  of  persons are aware of the study and our
request for  industry information.

     Frequently, trade  association  representatives  referred us to  spe-
cific individuals within  corporations who  might be  helpful to us or
have special experience or insight.  Follow-up  interviews of these
corporate representatives were  conducted.
                                 C-2

-------
                                       INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                       Appendix C
                  II.  INDUSTRY CONTACTS
 Alcoa
 The Aluminum Association
 Amax
 American Consulting Engineers Council
 American Insurance Association
 American Iron and Steel Institute                                               j  ?j
 American Mining Congress                                                        ];
 American Paper Institute                                                        '
 American Petroleum Institute
 Atlantic Richfield
 Battery Council International
 Business Roundtable
 California League of Food Processors
 Chemical Manufacturers Association
 Chemical Specialties Manufacturers Association
 Chevron
 Commercial Union Insurance
 Consolidated Coal                                                       t
 Dow Chemical Company
 E.I. dePont de Nemours & Co.
 Edison Electric Institute
 Electrical Power Research Institute
 Exxon Monsanto
 Food and Drug Law Institute
 Formaldihyde Institute
 Motor Vehicles Manufacturers Association
 National Solid Waste Management Association
 National Agricultural Chemicals Association
 National Association of Manufacturers
 National Federation of Independent Business
 National Food Processors Association
 National Forest Products Association
 National Insulation Certification Institute
 National Small Business Association
 NCASI—National Council of the Paper Industry for Air and Stream
    Improvement
 Pharmaceuticals Manufacturers Association
 Procter and Gamble
J.R. Sinplot
 Shell Oil
 Smith Kline Corporation
U.S. Chamber of Commerce
U.S. Steel
Water Pollution Control Federation
                           C-3

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix C
                         III.  EXAMPLE LETTER
 Dear
      I appreciate the interest in our study on indemnification that
 you expressed earlier today*  In response to your request for more
 information,  The Research Group is currently participating in a study
 of the feasibility and desirability of indemnifying affected indus-
 tries for significant compensable losses caused by EPA actions.
 Indemnification may also be appropriate as an incentive for industries
 to protect or enhance the environment or as a means of ensuring that
 EPA will consider the economic impact of regulatory acts.  This study
 will ultimately be presented by EPA to Congress as mandated by § 25(a)
 of the Toxic  Substances Control Act.

      We are reviewing all EPA programs including air, water, pesti-
 cides, waste  disposal,  and toxic substances to identify those EPA pro-
 grams to which Congress might apply an indemnification scheme.  The
 study includes an analysis of all environmental statutes, together
 with their legislative  history, implementation, and the potential eco-
 nomic impact  of government indemnification.  We are conducting Inter-
 views with Agency personnel, persons Involved in the legislative
 process,  and  public Interest representatives to obtain relevant infor-
 mation.   In order to present a well-balanced study, we are also
 seeking information and opinions from industry.

      To  date,  indemnification has not been favored by Congress as a
 general  regulatory relief or remedial mechanism.   Its use has been
 confined  to narrow circumstances under the Federal Insecticide,
 Fungicide and  Rodenticide Act,  as amended; agricultural indemnities to
 farmers  for losses due  to diseased livestock, contaminated milk,  etc.;
 the  Consumer Product Safety Act; and several occasions warranting a
 special Congressional indemnification bill*  It is most often proposed
 as a viable regulatory  mechanism in situations where an Agency has
 committed (or  may commit) a mistake which causes  substantial losses to
 a regulated party.   It  has also been suggested that indemnification
may  be appropriate where the Agency merely exercises bad judgment or
 later reverses a policy decision creating losses  within a given seg-
ment  of industry which  relied on the original policy decision.  Apart
 from a "fault"  base rational,  it has also been argued that indemnifi-
cation may  provide a mechanism for ensuring rapid, cooperative
response  in circumstances warranting emergency actions and thus assist
 In accomplishing an Important goal of a statute.   It might also serve
as a  disincentive to Agency use of certain extraordinary relief
mechanisms, except  in cases where alternatives are insufficient.
                                 C-4

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix C
Mr. XXXXXXXXXX
Date
Page Two
     In order to present a  thorough and  fully  informed  report  to
Congress on this issue, it  is very important that  representatives  of
industry, such as the Chemical Manufacturers Association,  consider the
potential impact of an indemnification program for regulated parties
and provide us your opinion and any other  relevant information that
would assist us in our consideration of  the iBsue.  If  your organiza-
tion or its members support the concept  of indemnifying regulated  par-
ties in certain situations, we would like  to document or discuss
specific factual events or  circumstances in which  compensation would
have been desirable, either as a matter  of fairness  or  to  obtain the
appropriate regulatory or legislative results.

     We will be pleased to  discuss the TSCA §  25(a)  study  or answer
questions you may have regarding situations possibly warranting indem-
nification.  Please contact me at (804)  977-5690.  We ask  that you
respond to us, at least informally, by February 17,  1982.  If  you
would like to submit a formal or written response, please  let  us know
so that a workable deadline may be established  that  will ensure full
consideration of your views in the draft report to be submitted to
EPA.
     Thank you very much for your Interest and cooperation.
forward to hearing from you.
We look
                                                                                        •
                                       Sincerely,
                                 C-5

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Appendix D
                             APPENDIX D
                  INDEMNIFICATION FINANCING SYSTEMS
                                                                 Pa
I.    Introduction ......................   D-2

II.   Financing System Options ................   D-3

      A.  Cash Payments From Regular Appropriations ......   D-4
      B.  Cash Payments From Special Appropriations After
          The Indemnifiable Event ...............   D-5
      C.  Cash Payments From Dedicated Tax Revenues ......   D-5
      D.  Cash Payments From a Revolving Fund .........   D-6
      E.  Direct Assumption of Liability by the Government . •   D-7
      F.  Special Tax Credit Resulting in Reduced Tax Revenues
          Revenues ......................   D-7

III.  Selection of an Appropriate Financing System ......   D-9

      A.  Purpose of the Indemnification Payment .......   D-9
      B.  Need for Immediate Payment ....... . .....   D-10
      C.  Frequency and Predictability of Events .......   D-10

IV.  Conclusion ........................   D-12

Exhibit 1 — Characteristics of Existing Indemnification
  Financial Systems ....... . ..............   D-13

Footnotes ...........................   D-14
                                 D-l

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix D
                           I.   INTRODUCTION
    Government programs can  be  financed  in a number of ways*   This
appendix provides a brief overview of  financing  alternatives  most per-
tinent to indemnification programs.  It  also provides  guidelines for
appropriately matching a financing system  to a particular indemnifica-
tion program.  A wealth of literature  exists on  the use of tax
credits, interest subsidies, and  similar devices for use as incen-
tives.  As much of the literature discusses the  relative advantage of
one devise over another in specific circumstances,  it  would be helpful
in designing the financing for  a  particular indemnification program.
This appendix is not intended as  a review  of all of this information,
but as an introduction to the possibilities and  their  implications for
indemnification.1
                                 D-2

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix  D
                     II.  FINANCING SYSTEM OPTIONS
    Financing  systems  have  two  basic components:

    •   Benefit distribution component — mechanism  by which economic
        benefits are transferred  to firms which suffer eligible
        losses.

    •   Funding component — mechanism by which the  economic resources
        to be  transferred to eligible firms are collected.

There are four basic options for  distribution of benefits;

    •   Cash payments — direct payments to eligible parties.

    •   Assumption of  liability — transfer of responsibility for  a
        potential liability to  the government.

    •   Tax assistance — selected tax relief for eligible  firms.

    •   Credit assitance — reduced cost of borrowing or  access to
        otherwise unattainable  loans.

There are also four basic options for funding programs:

    •   Appropriations by Congress from general tax  revenues -- either
        regular or special appropriations.

    •   Appropriations by Congress from dedicated or "ear-marked"
        revenue sources.

    •   Revolving fund account — budget initially may be provided by
        general tax revenues or ear-marked tax receipts but  fund is
        perpetuated by repayments (e.g., of loans) or recoveries of
        expended funds.

    •   Tax expenditures — reduced tax revenues resulting  from a
        special deduction, credit, deferral, or other special  tax
        concession.

    Each of the benefit distribution and funding options  has varia-
tions, resulting in many possible alternative structures  for a finan-
cing system.  For purposes of providing an overview  of the  range of
alternatives, we discuss the following systems:

    •   Cash payments  from regular appropriations.
pi
                                 D-3

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix D
    •   Cash payments  from  special  appropriations  after  the  indemnifi-
        able event.

    •   Cash payments  from  dedicated  tax  revenues.

    •   Cash payments  from  a  revolving  fund.

    •   Direct assumption of  liability.

    •   Special tax credit  resulting  in reduced  tax  revenues.

A.  Cash Payments From Regular Appropriations

    Under this alternative, indemnified parties  would  receive  govern-
ment checks in the amount for which they  are eligible.   These  payments
would be funded by appropriations from  general tax revenues.   The
appropriations could have many different  combinations  of features  with
respect to:  limits on the  amount of  funds available,  the agency's
authority (or lack thereof) to carry  over the unobligated funds  from
one year into the next, and the  timing  of the agency's requirements  to
request new budget authority.

    An example of a regularly funded  indemnification program is  USDA's
payment of compensation for contamination of milk, milk  products or
dairy cattle by pesticides  that  were  registered  under  FIFRA  at the
time of their use.2  The compensation awards are paid  by U.S.
Government checks, drawn on a USDA  general fund  expenditure  account.
In making its regular  budget  request  each fiscal year, USDA  includes
an amount to cover expected payouts plus  a margin  for  unexpected
claims.  At the end of each fiscal  year,  unobligated funds for this
account are returned to the Treasury.

    This alternative can be relatively  efficient in  handling frequent
and predictable compensation  claims.  Although this  alternative  is
flexiblle in the amounts of funding it  can handle, the expected
requirements should be large  enough and frequent enough  to justify the
permanent staff.  Failure to  provide  adequate funding  for expected
requirements will tend to disrupt normal  agency  operations (i.e.,  by
forcing normal operating budgets to be  diverted  to cover indemnifica-
tion claims) or to undermine  the incentive effects of  the program
since actual payment of claims cannot be  assured.

    Another example of this alternative is the Court of  Claims
Judgment Fund which is entirely  financed  by appropriations from
general revenue.  It is replenished from  time to time  in bulk  and
funding decisions seem unrelated to Individual claims  drawn  from it.
Many different kinds of claims are  paid from this  fund after decision
by the Court of Claims.  The  Mizokami Brothers were  paid from  it for
their losses associated with  an  erroneous FDA determination  that their
spinach was contaminated.
                                 D-4

-------
 B.
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix 0
Cash Payments From Special Appropriations After The Indemnl-
fiable Event
     This alternative differs froa the previous alternative in that the
 funding is requested after an indemnifiable event occurs.  By not
 seeking funding until after the event, there is less certainty that
 payment will be made but more certainty about the amount needed.
 Therefore, this alternative may be less effective than the previous
 alternative in motivating private parties or government agencies.
 However, the certainty may be increased by statutory guarantees or
 administrative pre-arrangements.

     An example of special appropriations is the Art and Artifacts
 Indemnification Program,^ administered by the National Endowment  for
 the  Arts (NEA).  Under this program,  the NEA is authorized to enter
 into agreements with museums and other institutions to Indemnify  these
 parties for loss or  damage to works of art, rare manuscripts, and
 other specified artifacts while on exhibition in the United States or
 overseas.   Any party that desires to  receive coverage for a particular
 exhibition must apply to the NEA.  Upon approval of the application,
 the  NEA and the party wishing to be covered enter into a formal indem-
 nity agreement, specifying the amount of coverage to be provided, sub-
 ject to certain statutory limitations.  No premiums are paid to the
 NEA  for this coverage.   In the event  of an eligible loss, the NEA
 would certify its investigation of the loss to Congress under a statu-
 tory arrangement. Congress would then appropriate money for compensa-
 tion.   Although appropriations are not made until after the loss, the
 certainty  of receiving  them is high because the statute allows NEA to
 pledge  the full faith and credit of the United States.

     For programs where  claims will occur on a non-routine and infre-
 quent basis and where the amounts of  claims are unpredictable,
 "after-the-fact" special appropriations usually will be more appropri-
 ate.  Backed by statutory authority to ensure eventual  payment, this
 approach provides crediblity to the program while avoiding unnecessary
 budgeting  of funds.

 C'.   Cash Payments From  Dedicated Tax "Revenues

    This alternative  differs from the  previous two in that revenues
 come  from  dedicated  sources such as special taxes or fees assessed on
 a designated class of individuals (i.e.,  the users of a certain
 product) or  companies or a designated  product (i.e.,  certain
 chemicals).   The revenues could be generated either continuously  to
meet  routine  and predicted requirements or periodically to meet non-
 routine and  infrequent  needs or to replenish the fund from previous
 payouts.

    The exact  relationship between the use of the funds and the
 individuals,  firms or products on which the taxes are assessed can
                                 D-5

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix D
vary  and  can  be  designed  in  such  a  way  as  to  create a variety  of
incentives  or disincentives  on  the  part of the taxed parties or the
users of  affected  products.

    In the  case  of Superfund, most  of the  fund comes from taxes on
certain chemicals  that are either directly or indirectly (as chemical
building  blocks) most frequently  associated with hazardous chemicals
that  come into contact with  the environment.   The primary objective of
this  approach to funding  was to create  an  incentive for companies  that
generate  these chemicals  to exercise greater  care in managing  them so
as to avoid spills or other releases into  the environment.

    A secondary  objective was to  free the  fund to some extent  from the
requirement to have new funds appropriated from Congress each  year.
However,  to prevent the loss of congressional control a portion of the
fund  still comes from general revenues  and the entire fund still is
subject to appropriations acts.

    To  establish this financing system,  several issues have to be
decided.  The first is whether the  assessments of firms, individuals
or products will be a regular, ongoing  activity,  almost like an
insurance program, or will occur  only after eligible losses.  Other
Issues  are the definition of the  types  of  firms that would be  assessed
and the basis for collecting the  assessment (e.g..  a per-unit  tax  on
certain types of goods paid by the  manufacturer).  These issues have
to be decided as the program is established.   Otherwise, funding may
never happen  because agreement as to the correct  magnitude of  the
claims  and as to the basis for contributing to the  fund will not
occur.

D.  Cash Payments From a  Revolving  Fund

    A revolving fund is a pool of money  out of which indemnity pay-
ments are made, which is  regularly  replenished through the repayment
or recovery of expended funds.  It  is not  unusual for such funds to be
initially funded and even continually supplemented  from general or
special appropriations or from special  assessments,  fees or penalties
from  parties affected by  or in some way  related to  the indemnifiable
events.

    The key aspect of revolving funds is that they  take on some form
of self reliance.  This reduces the need for  continued appropriations
and can provide an incentive for  good fiscal  management by the agen-
cies  responsible for the  program.   This  same  aspect tends to make  the
program somewhat independent of Congress,  thereby circumventing one of
the more effective means  of congressional  oversight.  For this reason,
expenditures from such funds still  may be  made subject to annual
appropriations acts even  though funds are  not coming from tax
revenues.
                                 D-6

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Appendix  D
     Section  311  of  the  CWA  and  Superfund  both  have  revolving  fund
characteristics.  Funds expended  for  cleanup activities  are  later
recovered  if possible  (i.e.,  if a responsible  party can  be found who
is  financially viable).

     This type of  system requires  a pre-existing  administrative  appara-
tus  to determine  the rules  for  who pays,  how much,  and when.

E.   Direct Assumption of Liability by the Government

     An assumption of the underlying risk  by the  government can  provide
a substantial economic  benefit  though no  payment is made.  The  govern-
ment might or might not establish a means of paying for  the  loss
before it occurs.

     The swine flu progran Is  a  good example.   Vaccine manufacturers
were so concerned about potential suits that they demanded protection.
The  Congress finally agreed to  make the sole cause  of action  one
against the  government.  In addition  to assuming the liability, the
Department of Justice has absorbed the considerable cost of defending
against the  four  thousand suits filed.

F.   Special  Tax Credit  Resulting  in Reduced Tax  Revenues

    A number of alternatives  exist involving the government foregoing
tax  revenues for  specific purposes.   Foregoing tax  revenues or making
indemnification payments have the same net effect on the amount of
government funds  available  for  other  purposes.

    Losses suffered by  reason of  agency actions  are usually eligible
for  deductions as ordinary  business expenses.  Thus, some tax
assistance is already available.   At  times Congress has  been  explicit
in declaring these losses eligible for a  deduction,  but  not for
indemnification.  The tax bill  of the summer of  1981 contained  such a
provision.   Truck certificates  which  had  formerly had considerable
value were rendered worthless when the trucking  industry was
de-regulated.  Congress used  the  tax  bill to make clear  Its view that
the  trucking firms could take a deduction for  the value  of the
certificates.6

    Tax credits could provide a much  greater benefit for losses con-
sidered more than ordinary expenses.   Eligible firms would be allowed
to reduce their tax liability by  some specified  amount.  An important
aspect of this alternative is the formula or set of guidelines  that
would specify the amount of the special tax credit.  The amount of the
credit would be related  to  the  eligible losses suffered.  For firms
with tax liabilities that are less than the amount  of the allowable
special tax  credit, the  program could be  designed to allow application
of the credit to  other  years  or could allow the  credit to be  sold to
another firm.
                                 D-7

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Appendix D
    Tax credit devices are administratively simple to operate,
reducing the complexity of trensfering an economic benefit to the
indemnified parties.  However, they should only be applied to very
large programs affecting many people or firms.  The required changes
in tax forms and reference materials can only be justified by a
widespread use of the new provision.
                                 D-8

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Appendix  D
          III.   SELECTION OF AN  APPROPRIATE  FINANCING  SYSTEM
    The  five  financing  system  alternatives  provide  a  sense  of  the
spectrum of possible systems.   In  the  discussion  of each, dimensions
along which it  seems most appropriate  to  differentiate  programs
emerged,  e.g.,  programs  relying on regular  appropriations may  be most
appropriate when  Inderanlfiable events  are predictable.   Exhibit 1  sum-
marizes  important characteristics  of the  financial  systems  of  existing                  j|l
indemnification programs.                                                              '•{'

    In this section, guidelines are presented  and discussed that can be
used to  help  define the  kind of financing alternative most  appropriate
for a particular  indemnification program.   The four aspects of an
indemnification program  are as follows:

    •    Purpose of the indemnification program;

    •    Cost  of the event relative to  an  individual party's financial
         capability;

    •    Need  for  indemnification payments to be immediately available;

    •    Frequency and predictability of events.

A.  Purpose of  the Indemnification Payment

    Indemnification programs usually exist  for some combination of  the
following objectives:

    •    Remedying Inequities;

    •    Creating disincentives to  inappropriate or  unreasonable
        action;

  -  •    Creating incentives for private parties or  otherwise facil-
        itating public goals.

    For  remedying inequities there is  no  Inherent bias  on the  selec-
tion of  funding methods.  The  key  is that relief  reach  the  correct
parties and in  an effective manner.  Cash payments  are  the  most direct                 j* |
distribution method, but tax credits or other  forms of  indirect relief                 '
can be Just as  valuable  and effective  under the right circumstances.

    The second  two objectives  are  somewhat  independent  of distribution
methods, but can be affected substantially  by  the choice of funding
methods.  For example, a program whose "objective is  to encourage
greater  industry care in handling  hazardous materials"  might choose
special  taxes on chemicals as  a source of revenues  for  indemnifying
                                 D-9

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix D
 parties against the voluntary assistance in cleanup activities.
 Likewise, a program aimed at discouraging ill-founded enforcement
 actions might draw some or all of its funds directly from agency
 operating budgets.

     Creating incentives for private parties also may depend upon the
 degree of certainty the parties feel.  If the indemnification program
 is established and funded in advance, private parties are more likely
 to believe in the program and thus to be motivated by it.  However,
 some parties require more certainty than others.  The contractor hired
 to clean up abandoned waste sites were satisfied with a contingent
 promise to consider indemnifying them when a loss occurs.  Swine flu
 vaccine manufacturers transfered their entire potential liability
 (except that resulting from negligence) before they began to manufac-
 ture the vaccine.

 B.  Weed for Immediate Payment

     The need for immediate receipt of funds to respond to the indem-
 nifiable event has a bearing on the choice of financing system.  Some
 indemnifiable events involve large costs to individuals or firms.  If
 immediate payment is not  forthcoming, serious economic harm may occui.
 Also,  for some incentive  programs, immediate payment is important to
 the success of the programs.

     The USDA animal disease  indemnification program5 provides an
 example of this point.  If the Secretary of Agriculture declares a
 national disease emergency for some animal  disease situation, funds
 for eradication and indemnification are made available from the
 Commodity Credit Corporation.  These funds  must subsequently be paid
 back through congressional appropriations.   The success of these
 disease emergency situations depends on quick government action and on
 industry cooperation.  That  cooperation is  in turn dependent on the
 availability of indemnification  funds to replace animals destroyed as
 part of the eradication program.   Thus,  speedy distribution of indem-
 nification payments is essential,  and hence,  the need for a funding
 arrangement such as borrowing  the  Commodity Credit Corporation funds.
 However,  the administrative  costs  necessary to provide quick response
 can only be justified by  the expectation of a series of losses.

 C.   Frequency and Predictability of  Events

     Another  major  factor  to consider in choosing the financing system
 is  the  likely  frequency and predictability  of  the indemnifiable
 events.  Some  events recur with a  regularity  that allows for esti-
mating  the  expected annual costs and requires  an administrative
 apparatus  to handle claims.  Other events might occur  so infrequently
 and  with widely varying costs  as to  make  the  total required payments
 unpredictable.   In  cases where the event  is  frequent,  up-front
 financing  through  insurance-like mechanisms or regular  appropriations
                                 D-10

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Appendix  D
can be appropriate.  Up-front financing becomes  less  attractive,  if
events occur infrequently and with widely varying  costs.
                                                                                       'ill
                                                                                       r"
                                 D-ll

-------
                                           INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                           Appendix D
                           IV.   CONCLUSION
    There are many financing mechanisms appropriate to indemnification
programs.  Choosing between them should be done in the context of a
particular program to ensure that the financing components are compat-
ible with the aims of that program.
                                     D-12


-------
                                                                          EXHI!

                                                CHARACTERISTICS OF EXISTING INDEMNIFICATION FINANCIAL SYSTEMS
USDA
EPA
Air
EPA
Clea
Program
Animal Disease
S Il3(b) Clean
Act
$ 202(a)(3)
n Water Act
Benefit
Distribution
Method
Cash payments
Cash payments
Cash payments
Funding
Method
Regular Approprl-
tlona
Appropriations to
Insufficient Claims
and Judgments Fund
Regular Appropria-
tions**
Purpose Costs of Need for
of Events Relative to Immediate
Program* Financial Capability Payment
3 Can be very high Yes
1,2 Low No
3 Uncertain No
Frequency and
Predictability
of Events
High
Low
Low
Unique
Aspects
Ability to borrow
funds from Comoodlty
Credit Corp. for
emergencies.


7   EPA 5 15 FIFIA
Cash payments     None established
                        1, 2, 3   Low-Moderate
                            No
                                           Low
                                                           Relied  on Industry
                                                           consolidation  of
                                                           claims  In Sllvex
                                                           case.
    Arts and Artifacts
Cash payments
Special Approprla-
atlons
Can be high
                                                                                                            No
Low
    EPA $ 311
    Clean Water Act
Cash payments
Special Approprla-
atlona plus
recoveries of funds
from responsible
parties
Can be high
                                                                                No
High
    *1 • Remedying Inequities*
     2 - Creating disincentives to inappropriate or unreasonable government action.
     3 - Creating incentives for private parties or otherwise facilitating a public goal.

    •* Payment of the indemnity la not a certainty.  If a grantee qualifies for the indemnity, they must still compete for the  funds with  other  potential  uses.

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Appendix D
                              FOOTNOTES

    *A more detailed discussion of this area can be found in "Identi-
fication and Preliminary Evaluation of Basic Financing System Options
for an EPA Indemnification Program," EPA, Prepared by American Manage-
ment Systems, Inc., December 1979.

    2Equal Opportunity Act of 196A, § 331(a) (rider to EOA).

    3Arts and Artifacts Indemnity Act, Public Law 94-158, 20 U.S.C.
§S 971 et aeq.

    4This assumes that the firms have played some part in bringing
about the situation requiring correction.
521 U.S.C.
                        , 134(d).
    626 U.S.C. 165 (note), 95 Stat. $ 266 (Aug. 13, 1981).
                                 D-14

-------
                                            INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                            Appendix E
                             APPENDIX E

                COSTS AND IMPACTS OF INDEMNIFICATION


                                                                 Page

I.    General Approach 	  E-2

II.   Cost of a TSCA Indemnification Program	E-5

      A.  Introduction	._	E-5
      B.  Costs	E-5
                                  c
          I.  Number of Banned Chemicals 	  E-5
          2.  Value of Inventory of Banned Chemical	E-6

      C.  Indemnification Impacts	E-9

          1.  Government	E-9
          2.  Manufacturers	E-9
          3.  Distributors	E-10
          A.  Users	E-10

III.  Some Indemnification Impacts of FIFRA Program 	 E-ll

      A.  Manufacturers	E-ll
      B.  Distributors	E-14
      C.  Users	E-15

Footnotes	E-16
1
i'

 ir
                                 E-l

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix E
                         I.   GENERAL APPROACH
     An  approach  to  estimating the cost and impact of an indemnifica-
 tion program  is  first  discussed in general, and then illustrated by
 application to a hypothetical TSCA indemnification program,  and a
 hypothetical  ban of a  pesticide under FIFRA.

     The costs to the government for an Indemnification program are
 largely a  function  of  (1)  the number of indemnifiable events and (2)
 the  cost of each event.  Estimates of the number of indemnifiable
 events  require:

     •   definition  of  what constitutes an Indemnifiable event,

     •   specificity of estimates by type of event, and

     •   estimates of expected values and likely upper bounds on the
         number of events of each type.

 Estimates  can be formed on the basis of a review of past experience o
 the  program,  review of similar programs, and opinions of experts.

    The cost  of  each indemnifiable event must also be estimated.
 These estimates  require:

    •   definition  of  the coverage of the program,

    •   data  on  costs  of similar events or other relevant data,  and

    •   data  by  type of indemnifiable event.

    Total  costs  of  a program  are estimated as the product of the
 number  of  events and the cost of each event.   A range can be estab-
 lished  around this  estimate using ranges determined while estimating
 the number and cost  of events.   The range of estimates provides  a
measure  of the uncertainty associated with the estimates.

    Only after the  costs are  reliably estimated can any analysis  of
 the impacts of the  cost be made.   The impact is the effect that  the
 cost  has on the  economic viability and behavior of the parties
directly and  indirectly affected.

    Although  the methodology  is  straightforward,  applying it is not.
The § 15 model limits  indemnifiable costs to inventory.   This is  a
comparatively concrete and verifiable measure.   It is not the only
measure of loss  that could be used.   However,  using any other measure
would add  to  the problems of  estimating cost.   For example if indemni
 fication is desired to compensate for all of  a company's loss when  a
                                 E-2

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix E
 .product is banned, some way would have to be found to value the
 research and development costs, the overhead sunk into the product,
 the future profits now lost, the cost of substitutes for customers,
 etc.   This would be much more difficult to reliably estimate since the
 lack  of definiteness leaves room for argument, and since the amounts
 would vary so much depending upon when in a product's life cycle the
 regulation was imposed, what kind of product it was, and whether the
 firm  was a manufacturer, distributor, or user.

    Estimating the frequency of unplanned events, especially new
 programs dissimilar to existing programs, may produce widely varying
 costs depending on assumptions.  This is especially true for programs
 involving events that occur infrequently.  Another complicating factor
 is  that the existence of the program itself may alter behavior of the
 government, individuals, or firmsC  For example, a government agency
 might be more likely to act in a situation which would result In
 indemnification payments because the affected parties would be less
 severely Impacted by the action with the availability of compensation.
 The government agency could also be envisioned to be less likely to
 act because it might have to make large indemnification payments*
 These impacts on behavior are difficult to pin down since they must be
 based on good cost estimates, but will also affect the cost of the
 program*   The descriptions of impacts also rely on the hypothesis that
 a government  agency faced with a potentially costly decision will
 react in the  same way that a "reasonable economic man" would.  This
 hypothesis may well be Incorrect.  The only thing that can be said
 with  some certainty is that the total cost of an indemnification
 program will  not approach the magnitude necessary to have an impact on
 the overall federal budget or the economy of the country.  The cost of
 a program might well be large enough to affect the budget of an indi-
 vidual  agency or program.

    Estimating costs of each event  is also difficult,  especially where
 there is  great variability between different events.   One can deal
 with  "average" events,  but if the number of events is  small, high
 uncertainty will be associated with the estimate of program costs.
 Another difficulty can occur in obtaining data for the analysis*  Some
 of the  key data items may not be publicly available and those with the
 data  may  not  cooperate  by supplying it to the analysis.  Assumptions
 and estimates can be made from the  data that are available, but the
 results will  be less certain than otherwise.

    The difficulty and  uncertainty  associated with estimates of indem-
 nification program costs  can be a deterrent to establishment of an
 indemnification program.   With high uncertainty in what the program
will  cost,  the actual costs could far exceed what is  estimated to be
 the expected  cost.   Over  a number of years, the estimate of expected
annual  costs  could  be expected to more closely approximate the running
average of  the actual costs than would the expected average cost
approximate the actual  cost for any particular year.   It could be dif-
                                  E-3

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix E
flcult to  "sell" a program with  greatly  fluctuating  costs  even  if  the
expected average annual costs approximated  the  actual  average annual
costs.

    There  are cost continment techniques  that could  be used  to  over
come the problem of uncertainty, though  they would limit the amount of
indemnification received and thus po-ssibly  reduce the  effectiveness of
the program.  A ceiling can be placed on  the size of individual
claims, or on the amount of expenditures  that the program  could make
in any one year4  The indemnification program might  only be  authorized
for a year or two to give Congress an opportunity to reconsider based
on actual experience.

    In part II of this appendix, the costs  of a hypothetical TSCA
indemnification program are analyzed, and in part III  an attempt is
made to analyze the impacts of a hypothetical pesticide ban  under
FIFRA.
                                 E-4

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Appendix  E
              II.  COST OF A TSCA INDEMNIFICATION PROGRAM
A.   Introduction

     The Toxic Substances Control Act  (TSCA) does not  provide  indemni-
fication  for any costs  incurred by  individuals and firms as a result
of TSCA actions taken by EPA.  In this  paper, we analyze the  costs
that would be associated with  a hypothetical TSCA indemnification
program — one patterned after the  Federal, Insecticide, Fungicide,
and  Rodenticide Act (FIFRA)  §  15 indemnification program.

     We hypothesize that the  TSCA program would -apply  only  to  chemicals
which have made it through the TSCA § 5 premanufacture  notification
(PMN) review process and for which the  manufacture, processing, dis-
tribution, use, or disposal  is subsequently prevented by EPA  action
under § 6 or 7.  Indemnification would  be  provided to compensate for
the  cost  of the chemical held  by any  individuals or firms  at  the time
of the EPA action.

B.   Costs

     The cost to EPA of a TSCA  indemnification program of this type is
a function of the number of  chemicals likely to be banned  and the cost
of the Inventory in those chemicals when the bans are Imposed.  Each
of these  factors will be discussed  in turn.

     1.  Number of Banned Chemicals

        The number of chemicals likely  to  be banned is  a function of
the  thoroughness of the PMN  review  and  the frequency  that  EPA uses
product bans with no inventory sell.off as a regulatory device.  The
thoroughness of the review process  is of course relative.  Because of
this, it  is useful to compare  the PMN review process  with  the pesti-
cide preregistration review  process that occurs under FIFRA.   With a
sense of  how these review processes compare, we can review the FIFRA
registration cancellation experience and analyze what general implica-
tions it  might have for the  number  of chemicals that  make  it  through
the PMN process and would subsequently  be  regulated.  Of course, there
are  basic differences between  pesticides and other chemicals  which
limit the usefulness of comparisons between the review  processess.

        In a previous comparison1 of the PMN and FIFRA  review
processes, we concluded that the two processes are very different.
The most  significant difference is  that TSCA requires none of the
testing that Is the backbone of the FIFRA  process.  The testing
required  for approval of a new pesticide is quite lengthy  and costly.
The PMN process, on the other  hand, is  intended as an Initial
screening and reporting mechanism and is not Intended to provide a
examination of all risks.
                                 E-5

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix E
         Even with the thorough review process before pesticides are
 registered,  there still have been over ten pesticide registrations
 cancelled or notices of intent to cancel issued.  This indicates that
 a preregistration review process does not ensure that unreasonably
 unsafe pesticides will be prevented from being registered.

         This FIFRA experience implies that some number of chemicals
 that make it through the PMN review process will be subsequently regu-
 lated by EPA.  The FIFRA experience, however, cannot reasonably be
 used to estimate the number  of chemicals involved.  This is because
 pesticides by their nature are more toxic than the average chemical
 and therefore cannot be considered representative of chemicals in
 general.   The criteria for subsequent EPA regulation are also differ-
 ent for pesticides than they are for other chemicals.

        EPA  has to date initiated very few regulatory actions under
 § 6 of TSCA.   None of these  § 6 actions have been directed at chemi-
 cals that have made it through the PMN review process.  Because most
 of the chemicals now on the  market were introduced before TSCA was
 implemented,  we would expect to see over the next decade very few EPA
 actions taken against chemicals that have been reviewed prior to com-
 mercial production.   Additionally,  product bans represent an extreme I
 regulatory action and would  be expected to occur infrequently.  For
 these reasons,  over the long term an assumption of one product ban
 every two years involving a  chemical that made It through the PMN pro-
 cess could be considered a conservative upper bound on the actual
 number of such bans that will occur over time.

     2.  Value of Inventory of  Banned Chemical

        The value of  the inventory of a banned chemical depends on the
 chemical's production volume,  price and use patterns.  In a previous
 analysis^ of  a sample of 1,459  chemicals from the TSCA Chemical
 Inventory which were  candidates for a § 8 reporting rule,  we deter-
 mined the distribution of  these chemcials across a series of produc-
 tion categories.  This  information is shown in Exhibit 1.   If we
 assume  that all  chemicals  within a production category are produced at
 the  production  volume represented by the midpoint of the category,  the
 average production volume  can  be calculated to be approximately 88
million pounds.
                                 E-6

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix E
                               EXHIBIT  1

      PRODUCTION  VOLUME  DISTRIBUTION  OF SAMPLE OF 1,459  CHEMICALS
                   FROM  THE  TSCA  CHEMICAL INVENTORY
      Production Range  (Ibs)
              0
           1,000
          10,000
        100,000
      1 million
     10 million
     50 million
    100 million
    500 million -
      greater than
 1
10
      1,000
     10,000
    100,000
    million
    million
 50 million
100 million
500 million
  1 billion
 1 billion
Percentage of Chemicals
	in Category I	a/

          11.5
           7.8
          11.2
          14.4
          15.8
          14.8
           7.0
          13.0
           2.4
           2.1
    a/  These percentages relate only  to  the  chemicals  in  the  sample
of 1,459 for which production volume was  reported.

Source;  "Analysis of TSCA $ 8(a) Small Manufacturer  Exemption,"
          ICF Incorporated, May 1981.

        There are three reasons why this  average  may  be higher than
the average production volume of chemicals  that have  been  banned  after
having made it though the PMN process.  Firstly,  because economic
impact would be factored into consideration of a  product ban,  we  would
expect higher volume chemicals to be less likely  to be  banned  than
lower volume chemicals.  Secondly, the sample of  1,459  chemicals  may
have been biased toward larger production volumes because  these chemi-
cals were selected on the basis of the degree of  hazard they poten-
tially presented.  This means that larger production  volume chemicals
would be over-represented because, everything else being equal, they
represent more hazard than do lower production volume chemicals.  The
third reason that the 88 million pounds might be  biased upwards as an
estimate of the average production volume of  PMN  "cleared" chemicals
that are subsequently banned, relates  to  the  difference In age of the
1,459 chemicals versus PMN "cleared" chemicals.   The  production volume
of a chemical typically follows a life-cycle  as shown in Exhibit  2.
Newer chemicals will tend to be of lower production volume than more
mature chemicals.  Therefore, one would expect the production  volumes
for the 1,459 chemicals to be higher than a sample of relatively  new
chemicals.  However, over time the universe of chemicals which have
"cleared" the PMN process will Increase and their age profile  will
become closer to the age profile of the 1,459 chemical  sample.  For
purposes of this analysis, we will use the  88 million pound average,
recognizing that it probably is an inflated estimate.
                                 B-7

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix E
                               EXHIBIT 2
                      TYPICAL CHEMICAL LIFE-CYCLE
         Volume
         Growth
                                              Mature
Aging
                                 Growth
                     Embryonic
                                         Time

Source;  "Impact of TSCA Proposed Premanufacturing Notification
          Requirements," Arthur D. Little,  Inc.,  December  1978.

        The volume of manufacturers' sales  associated  with the  88     *
million pounds of chemicals can be estimated by multiplying by  the
average price of a pound of chemicals.  Most,commercial  chemicals sell
for under $1 per pound.•*  For purposes of this analysis  we will assume
a $.75 per pound price for the average chemical.  Therefore sales for
the average chemical equals $66 million.

        In 1979, for a sample of 75 chemical companies,  the average
ratio of sales to inventories was 6.9.   Applying this ratio to the
$66 million in sales for the average chemical yields $9.6  million in
manufacturers' inventories associated with  the average chemical.  Add-
itional inventories in the chemical are held by distributors and
users.

        Most chemicals are intermediate materials sold to  other manu-
facturers who process them into end products.5  Also,  most large
chemical users buy direct from the manufacturers; less than 122 of all
chemicals are sold through distributors.^  We assume that  the inven-
tory holding practices of distributors and users  is the  same as the
manufacturers.  We therefore assume that the distributors  and users
combined hold an additional $9.6 million in inventories  of the  average
chemical.

        We assume that the values of inventory we have estimated are
based on firms valuing their inventories on retail prices.   With that
assumption we can use the same factors EPA used to estimate inventory
cost in calculating the level of indemnification  to be payed in the
Silvex registration cancellation under § 15 of FIFRA.  In  the Silvex
situation, the cost of the manufacturer's inventory was  set at  701 of

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix E
 the  Invoice  price,  and  the  cost  of  the  users'  and  distributors'  inven-
 tory was  set  at  115%  of  the invoice  price.   The  cost  of  manufacturers'
 inventories  of  the  average  chemical  are  therefore  $6.7 million and  the
 cost of  the  distributors' and users'  inventories are  $11 million.   The
 total  cost of inventories is  therefore  $17.7 million.

        We have  assumed  that every  two  years there will  be  one produc-
 tion ban  involving  the  payment of indemnification  funds  for the  cost
 of inventory.  Therefore $17.7 million  in  indemnification will be
 paid out  every two  years or an average  of  about  $9 million  per year.

 C.   Indemnification Impacts

     1.  Government
                                 c
        It is not clear how the  requirement  to pay indemnification  for
 inventory losses associated with product bans  would influence  the
 government's decision regarding  the  ban.   Product  bans are  an  extreme
 regulatory action that are  unlikely  to  be  used except where their need
 is clearly warranted.  This would imply  that an  indemnification  provi-
 sion would not have a significant influence on whether or not  to
 declare the ban.  However,  there may  arise decisions  regarding product
 bans that are close calls.  The availability of  Indemnification  funds
 could  result in  not banning the chemical because of the  need to  pay
 out  a  large amount  of compensation  to the  industry.  The availability
 of indemnification  funds could also  have the opposite effect in
 influencing the  government  to ban the chemical because the  economic
 impact to the industry would be softened,  though this does  not seem
 likely.

     2.  Manufacturers

        The decision to invest in the production of a new chemical
 involves  consideration of the expected  returns from that investment
 and  the uncertainty associated with  those  returns.  An Indemnification
 provision which would cover the cost  of an Inventory  loss as a result
 of a product ban under TSCA would make,  investment  in  new chemicals
 more attractive.

        The degree  to which an indemnification provision would
 increase  the attractiveness of investment  in new chemicals  is  a  func-
 tion of the ratio of the amount of  losses  covered  by  indemnification
 to the amount of total losses.  In our analysis of the FIFRA § IS
 indemnification  provisions, we found  that, for the pesticide we
 studied,  the indemnification program  should not  significantly  alter
 the  initial investment decision.  This  same conclusion applies to
 chenicals similar to the pesticide we studied.  It is likely that with
 product bans an uncommon regulatory  approach,  manufacturers' invest-
ment behavior in new chemicals should not  change significantly.
                                 E-9

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix E
    3.  Distributors

        As we have pointed  out, distributors  handle  only a small  part
of chemical sales.  Their losses due  to  a  product  ban  would be  mostly
their inventory cost.  If this  is  indemnified,  their losses would be
small.  Without indemnification, they would tend to  hold smaller
inventories and perhaps diversify  more in  the products they handle.
However, as product bans do not occur often,  distributors are unlikely
to significantly alter their behavior.

    A.  Users

        The primary users of chemicals are chemical  manufacturers
themselves.  Without indemnification, these users  would tend to hold
smaller inventories and might be less likely  to use  chemicals that
have a high probability of  being banned.   However, the predominant
factor in choosing between  chemicals  would relate  to how well they
serve the users' purposes.
                                                                                *
                                                                                L
                                 E-10

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix E
          III.   SOME  INDEMNIFICATION IMPACTS OF FIFRA PROGRAM
     The  direct  benefit  of  indemnification to qualifying manufacturers,
 distributors, and  users is the  payment  of the cost  of finished pesti-
 cide inventory  in  stock at the  time  of  cancellation that cannot be
 sold or  used.   Cost  is  not defined  in the statute;  however it may not
 exceed the  fair market  value  of the  inventory.   The cost of such
 inventory is different  for each part of the  pesticide distribution
 chain.   In  the  Silvex situation,  the cost of the manufacturer's inven-
 tory was set at 70%  of  the invoice  price, and the cost of the users'
 and  distributors'  inventory was set  at  115%  of  the  Invoice price.  We
 have not been able to determine the  basis for these percentages, how-
 ever they appear consistent with  price  markups  in the pesticide
 industry.

 A.   Manufacturers

     The  impacts of pesticide  registration cancellations on the manu-
 facturers are determined by the timing  of the cancellation.  A manu-
 facturer must typically invest  large amounts of  funds in research and
 development, production, and  promotion  over  a period of years before  a
 pesticide begins to  be  profitable.   For many years, the cash flow
 from the investment  is  negative.  One estimate  is that sales begin for
 the  average pesticide eight years after it is first synthesized.
 Therefore,  if a pesticide  is  cancelled  soon  after registration,  the
 manufacturer will  take  a heavier  loss than if the cancellation occurs
 later in the pesticide's life cycle.

     Also, a manufacturer's inventory of a pesticide varies over the
 year because while production is  relatively  constant, usage is
 seasonal.  Generally speaking,  inventories are  highest immediately
 before the growing season  and lowest  immediately afterwards.  Hence,  a
 registration cancellation  immediately before the season will result in
 higher potential inventory losses to  manufacturers  than would a
 registration cancellation  after the  season.

     In making investment decisions regarding the production of a new
 pesticide, a manufacturer  considers  the expected return from the
 investment and  the uncertainty  (risk) associated with that return.
Because returns and  the risks associated  with those returns are posi-
tively correlated  (i.e., high returns are usually associated with high
 risks), a manufacturer  must accept some risk to  achieve a desired
 level of expected  return.

    To a manufacturer of pesticides,  the  possibility that EPA might
cancel a registration at some future  time translates into increased
uncertainty (risk) associated with investment in a  particular
pesticide. The  fact  that Indemnification  payments might be available
                                 E-ll

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix E
 (under certain conditions) for some cancellations theoretically could
 provide some incentive to a manufacturer to invest more in pesticide
 research and development and production than would otherwise be
 invested.   This is because some of the investment risk is removed by
 the availability of the indemnification payments.

     The degree to which the availability of indemnification payments
 for inventory losses may affect manufacturers'  investment decisions
 can be assessed to some extent through analysis of the expected cash
 flows  associated with a typical pesticide.   Framing the analysis in
 this way can provide important Insights in this regard.  However, a
 full assessment of the impact of indemnficiation payments on manufac-
 turers'  investment decisions would involve detailed study of a repre-
 sentative  sample of pesticides.  Perhaps some particular category of
 pesticides (e.g.,  moderate volume pesticides involving small research
 and development costs) would be more (less) sensitive to the avail-
 ability of indemnification payments than would other categories.  Such
 an  approach was beyond the scope of our available time or budget.

     Exhibit 3 provides cash flow information of the insecticide
 TH  6040.   TH 6040 was discovered in 1969,  and extensive research and
 development expenditures were necessary before  the first registration
 was obtained at the end of 1975.   Presumedly the pesticide will be a
 viable,  commercial product until the end of the century.  We can apply
 the net  present value (NPV) method,  commonly used in business,  to
 determine  the viability and profitability of an investment,  to  analyze
 alternative registration cancellation scenarios and the Impact  of
 indemnification payments on the initial Investment decision. With
 NPV, the timing of the cash flow and the discount rate assumptions can
 be  as  Important as the magnitude of  the case flows themselves.

    The  relative  riskiness of an investment project is reflected in
 the discount  rate  assumptions;  in essence,  the  higher the risk,  the
 higher  the  discount rate.   Intuitively,  this means that future
 dollars, being more uncertain,  are valued less;  the more uncertainty
 associated  with the future,  the higher the  discount rate. For  the
 development  of  commodity type pesticide chemicals,  the discount  rates
 often  range  from 10 to 15  percent.8   For new innovative high-risk
 pesticides,  they can range from 15 to 25 percent.   In the NPV analysis
 of  TH 6040, we  bound the analysis by using  discount rates of both 10
 and 20 percent.9   The discounted  cash flows from the pesticide,  given
 no  cancellations,  are shown in Exhibits 4 and 5*   If no cancellations
occur, TH 6040  is  expected to be  very profitable.

    The effects of  cancellation one,  five,  and  10 years after regis-
 tration are  shown  in Exhibits 6 and  7.   Inventory losses are not shown
because they  depend on the inventory level  assumptions.   Each pesti-
cide manufacturing  plant is  assumed  to be worth 402 of its original
 cost as salvage value.^  This  is a  very rough  estimate,  subject to a
 large variance.  Clearly,  a  plant could be  worth a great deal more
                                 E-12

-------
                                                                BIT  3
                                       EXPECTED CASH  FLOWS OF  TYPICAL  PESTICIDE  -  TH  60HO
                                                         T5in  thousands)


















ni
i
Is)
p>













Year
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
197U
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1981

1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
199U
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
Production
( Ibs)
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
3,675
79,163
223.99*4
370,356
682,106
1,155,788
1,557,338
1,889,013
2,220,7l4l4

2,388,700
2,392,881
2,395,288
2,355.39'*
2.2714,256
2,192,200
2.018,181
1,752.188
1,1485.206
1,2014,725
9*48.225
679,850
1455,075
273,0l4«4
91,013

RAD Costs
-875.0
-875.0
-26U.O
-5*40.0
-1,060.0
-1,230.0
1.U50.0
-6U2.0
-359.0
-30.0
-30.0
-30.0




















                                     Sales
                                   at $16/lb
                                       58.8
                                    1.266.6
                                    3,583.9
                                    5.925.7

                                   10.913.7
                                   18.1492.6
                                   214,917.14
                                   30,22«4.2
                                   35,531.9

                                   38,219.2
                                   38,286.1
                                   38,3214.6
                                   37,686.3
                                   36,388.1

                                   35,075.2
                                   32,290.9
                                   28,035.0
                                   23,763.3
                                   19,275.6

                                   15.171.6
                                   10.877.7
                                    7.281.2
                                    14,368.7
                                    1.1456.2
 Product ion
    and
Di stribut ion
    Costs
     -191.1
     -6014.2
   -1.396.8
   -2,197.7

   -14,0714.7
   -6,666.8
   -9,035.2
  -11.021.3
  -12,836.6

  -13,755.7
  -13.778.6
  -13,791.0
  -13,573.5
  -13,129.5

  -12,680.14
  -11,728. 1
  -10,101.5
   -8,6140.5
   -7,003.1

   -5,531.0
   -14,062.14
   -2.661.3
   -1,665.2
     -668.1
Capi taI
 Costs I/
-1,125.0

-1,125.0
    0
    0
    0
-1,125.0

 1,125.0
    0
-1.125.0
-1,125.0
    0

    0
    0
    0
    0
    0

    0
    0
    0
    0
    0

    0
    0
    0
    0
 2,700.0
 Pre-Tax
Cash Flow

   -875.0
  Cross
After-Tax
Cash Flow

   -1437.5
-875.0
-264. 0
-5140.0
-1,060.0
-2.355.0
-2,575.0
-77U.3
303.14
2,157.1
2,573.0
5, 6814.0
11,825.8
114,757.2
18,077.9
22,695.3
214,1463.5
2M.507. 5
214,533.0
214,113.0
23,259.0
22,395.0
20,563.0
17,9314.0
15,123.0
12.273.0
9,6141.0
6,815.0
U.620.0
2,7014.0
3,«487.1
-1437.5
-132.0
-270.0
-503.0
-1,177.5
-1.287.5
-387.2
151.7
1,078.6
1,286.5
2,81(2.0
5,912.9
7,378.6
9,039.0
11.3147.7
12,232.0
12,25U.O
12,266.0
12,056.0
11,629.0
11, 197.0
10,281.0
8,967.0
7,561.14
6,136.0
14.820.0
3.1408.0
2310.0
1,352.0
1,7143.6
     Source:  SRI, New Innovative Pesticides. 1977, with additions cited  in the footnotes below.

     I/Three $2.25 million plants was assumed to have been required to manufacture the pesticides.
was assumed to be UO percent of the original cost.
     2/Ten year straight line depreciation, assuming a 50 percent tax rate.
 After-Tax
Deprec i ;i t ion
 Benefits 2/

      0

      0
      0
      0
      0
    56.3

   112.5
   112.5
   112.5
   112.5
   168.8

   225.0
   225.0
   281 .3
   337.5
   281.3

   225.0
   225.0
   225.0
   225.0
   168.8

   112.5
   112.5
    56.3
      0
      0

      0
      0
      0
      0
      0
   Net
After-Tax
Cash Flow
                                            -1437. 5

                                            -1437.5
                                            -13?.0
                                            -270.0
                                            -503.0
                                          -1,121.3

                                          -1, 175.0
                                            -27<4.7
                                             26'4. 2
                                           1,119.1
                                           1.M55.3

                                           3,067.0
                                           6,137.9
                                           7,659.9
                                           9,376.5
                                          11,629.0

                                          12,1457.0
                                          12,1479.0
                                          12,1491 .0
                                          12,281.0
                                          11,798.0

                                          11,310.0
                                          10,3914.0
                                           9,023.0
                                           7,561.14
                                           6.136.0

                                           14,820.0
                                           3,1408.0
                                           2,310.0
                                           1,352.0
                                           1,7143.6
                                                     Salvage value  of  the plants

-------
                                  EXHIBIT 6
                     EFFECTS OF CANCELLATION ON THE NPV
           OF CASH FLOWS. BEFORE VALUE OF INVENTORY IS CONSIDERED*
                               ($ in thousands)
                        No         Cancellation
                   Cancellation    After 1 Year
                                Cancel-         Cancel-
                             lation After    lation After
                                5 Years        10 Years
Cumulative Cash
  Flows (less
  salvage value
  of plant)

Salvage Value
41,833
-4,619
 1,930
     ^Assumes 10 percent discount rate.
                                  EXHIBIT  7
                     EFFECTS OF CANCELLATION ON THE NPV
           OF CASH FLOWS. BEFORE VALUE OF INVENTORY IS CONSIDERED*
                               ($ in thousands)
22,317
of Plant(s)
NPV
78
41,911
677
-3,942
923
2,853
860
23,177
Cumulative Cash
  Flows (less
  salvage value
  of plant)

Salvage Value
  of Plant(s)

NPV
                        No         Cancellation
                   Cancellation    After 1 Year
11,989


     9

11,998
-5,368


   520

-4,848
                                Cancel-         Cancel-
                             lation After    lation After
                                5 Years        10 Years
-1,497


   503

  -994
 7,056


   303

 7,359
     *Assumes 20 percent discount rate.
                                      E-12d

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix E
 than 40X of its original cost if it can serve,  with minimal change-
 over, to produce another pesticide or chemical.   A plant could be
 worth much less if the machinery,  building and  location are unsuitable
 for production of an alternative.   The results  would not be materially
 affected for TH 6040 if a 0 or 100 percent salvage value were
 assumed. *•

     Research and development expenditures for one pesticide often can
 benefit  the development of other pesticides.  In an ideal and most
 certainly non-existent cost accounting system,  the percentage of
 research and development expenditures that would benefit other pesti-
 cides would be allocated to these  pesticides.  We assume that this has
 been done in the case of TH 6040,  although it would not materially
 affect the analysis if the proper  allocations had not been made.

     Exhibits 6 and 7, before considering inventory effects, show the
 significant impacts of a cancellation one year  after registration.
 Even a cancellation 10 years after registration  reduces the NPV signi-
 ficantly.  However, the effects  of finished inventory in stock at the
 time of  suspension can be indemnified.  To determine those effects, we
 must estimate the levels of inventory that would exist at the time of
 suspension.

     Immediately before the Northern Hemisphere  pesticide application
 season,  pesticide inventories are  at a peak.  Industry representatives
 have stated that inventory could amount to as much as 100Z of a year's
 production.^  Immediately after the Northern Hemisphere application
 season,  the pesticide inventories  are apt to  be  at the lowest levels.
 We  will  assume 10Z of a year's production to  be  a safe lower bound,
 502 as a seasonable average inventory level,  and 100Z as an upper
 bound.

     Exhibit 8  shows the after tax  value of the  pesticide inventory,
 assuming the manufacturer receives the full wholesale price of $10 a
 pound (62.5Z of retail) in Indemnity payments.   We assume that the
 TH  60AO  manufacturer Is in effect  "selling" its  inventory at the
 wholesale price,  therefore they  make a profit on the transaction.^
'Without  indemnification,  the manufacturer loses  the variable costs of
 producing the  inventory (remember  the fixed costs have already been
 counted).   Depending on what assumptions are  chosen, the indemnifica-
 tion program would raise  the after-tax NPV of TH 6040 from $24,000 to
 $4,810,000.

     These are  not insubstantial  sums, but the crucial question is
 their impact on the investment decisions of the  firm.  In other words,
 how much is the expected  NPV of  an investment changed by the indemni-
 fication program.   Cancellation  of a pesticide regulation,  after all,
 Is  a rare  event;  only nine of any  significance have occurred since
 1970.14
                                  E-13

-------
                                  EXHIBIT 8

                NET PRESENT VALUE OF INVENTORY GAINS/LOSSES:
                      WITH AND WITHOUT INDEMNIFICATION
                               ($ in thousands)

                         Inventory Levels as a Percentage of Production
10% Discount
Rate
1
Years After 5
Registration 10

WITH INDEMNIFICATION |
i
100%
249
3032
3902
50%
125
1516
1951
10% |
25 |
303 |
390 j
i

j )
| WITHOUT INDEMNIFICATION j
i
I 100%
1
1 -71
| -706
| -907
50%
-35
-353
-454
10% |
-7 |
-71 |
-91 |
1
    20% Discount
        Rate
Years After
Registration
1
h~
1 1
5 |
10 I
i
100%
191
1652
1374
50%
96
826
687
10%
19
165
137
i
 100%
50%
10%
  -54   |    -27   |    -5    |
 -384   I   -192   I   -38    |
 -319   I   -160   I   -32
	1	1	i
                                      E-13a

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix E
     We will assume a high expected cancellation rate for TH 60AO to
 magnify the effects of the indemnification program on the NPV.   We
 will assume that the probability of cancellation increases as the
 pesticide becomes older,  its use becomes more widespread, and any
 chronic health effects would have had time to develop.   We assume a IX
 chance of cancellation a  year after registration, a 5%  chance of can-
 cellation five years after registration, and a 10% chance of cancella-
 tion ten years after registration.  For purposes of illustration, we
 assume a 10% discount rate and an inventory level of SOX of the pro-
 duction of the year following cancellation.

     Exhibit 9 shows that,  even with these very high cancellation
 probabilities, the expected NPV of TH 6040 is only increased $336.00
 by  the indemnification.   This amount, less than IX of the expected
 NPV,  is not large enough  to significantly influence decision making
 for most companies.

     The conclusions of this analysis  agree with anectodal evidence
 gathered from industry representatives,  both during the original leg-
 islative hearings and in  recent Interviews.^  The current indemnifi-
 cation program should have had little effect on the amount of money
 invested in the research  and development,  production, or marketing of
 pesticides of the type represented by the  pesticide we  have analyzed.
 For pesticides with lower  research and development or capital costs,
 overall losses associated  with cancellation would be more senitive to
 inventory losses.   On the  other hand,  pesticides with expected  low
 research and  development  costs are likely  to be more similar to chemi-
 cals  currently registered  and thus are probably less likely to  be more
 similar to chemicals  currently registered  and thus are  probably less
 likely to be  cancelled than a truly innovative pesticide such as
 TH  6040.   Furthermore,  a  pesticide would have to have very much lower
 research and  development  and capital  costs than TH 6040,  even assuming
 identical expected cancellation probabilities,  for the  availability of
 indemnification payments  to make much difference in the investment
 decision.

 B.  Distributors

    The distributors  of pesticides typically invest very little except
 the cost  of inventory in any given pesticide.   If  a pesticide regis-
 tration is cancelled,  they can usually sell a substitute product.   The
 substitute product may be  more  or  less profitable  and the routine of
business  may  be disrupted,  but  on  the  whole the majority of the cost
of cancellation  to a  distributor is captured in their cost of inven-
tory.   The §  IS  indemnification program  is  aimed at reimbursing these
costs.  Without  indemnification, distributors would have incentives to
keep  inventories  low  and to diversify  into  handling more different
 pesticides.   Any higher risk of loss would  be  translated into higher
retail  prices,  i.e.,  they  would require  a  higher return to accept  the
higher  risk.
                                 E-14

-------
                             EXHIBIT 9
               IMPACT OF INDEMNIFICATION ON THE NET
                   PRESENT VALUE OF A PESTICIDE
                          ($ in thousands)
With Indemnification
                         Without Indemnification
                                                 Amount Gained by
                                                   Indemnification
Pro'bab-
 ility
0.84
0.10
0.05
0.01
x
x
X
X
Amount
41,911 = 34,205
25,128 =  2,513
 4,368 =    218
-3,817 =    -36
 NPV    $36,898
Probab-
ility
0.84 x
0.10 x
0.05 x
0.01 x
Amount
41,911 =
22,723 =
2,500 =
-3,977 =
34,205
2,272
125
-40
$36,562
       $336 (Amount Saved with Indemnification)
     	  = 0.9% of original NPV
     $36,562 (Original NPV without Indemnification)      is indemnity

Assume:   10% discount factor
          50% of production in inventory
          10% probability of imminent hazard cancellation after 10 years
          5% probability of imminent hazard cancellation after 5 years
          1% probability of imminent hazard cancellation after 1 year
                                  E-14a

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Appendix  E
C.  Users

    The users of pesticides  invest  relatively  little  in  pesticides.
Farmers are major users and  less  than  102 of their annual  variable
costs per acre are pesticide  purchases. "  However, if a pesticide of
choice is not available,  the  farmer will have  to depend  on an  alter-
native, probably inferior pesticide until an adequate substitute  is
available.  Therefore, the losses to a farmer  from a  registration can-
cellation are predominantly dependent  on the annual losses sustained
by using an inferior alternative  and the number of years the alter-
native must be employed.  One would expect that the amount of  money
invested in the cancelled pesticide itself to  be a small percentage of
the total losses.  Indemnification against these losses  would  not sig-
nificantly alter a farmer's choice of  pesticides.  The absence of such
indemnification payments might Influence some  farmers to hold  less
pesticides in storage for future  needs.

    An illustrative example of the registration cancellation losses to
a farmer is provided by the case  of Sllvex use on sugar  cane in
Florida.^   For three years  after the cancellation of Silvex, the
pesticide 2,4-D would have to be  substituted on Florida  sugar  cane
resulting in average yield loss.
                                E-15

-------
                                       EXHIBIT 10
                  CANCELLATION AND INDEMNIFICATION EFFECTS ON A USER:







Pesticide
Silvex
2,4,0


Amount
of Pes-
ticide
Used
(lb/
acre)
1
2
SILVEX VS


Pes-
ticide
Unit
Cost
($/lb)
5.50
2.13
. 2,4-D USE ON FLORIDA SUGAR CANE


Pes-
ticide
Cost
($/
acre)
5.50
4.26


Private
Appli-
cation
Cost
($)
2.00
2.00
Total
Pes-
ticide
Cost
Per
Acre
($)
7.50
6.26


Tons of
Cane
Yield
Per
- Acre
30.4
21.3



Value
of
Cane
($/ton)
20.06
20.06



Pre-Tax
Revenue
($/
acre)
609.82
427.28
                  Pretax Revenue per Acre:
        Less difference in pesticide cost:
     Difference in gross revenue per acre:
$609.82
-427.28
$182.54
-1.24
Silvex
2,4-D
                        $181.30
Assumptions:
For 3 years after cancellation, no substitute except 2,4-D.
After 3 years a perfect substitute.
Transition costs are zero.
Prices hold constant.
No shifting of cane growth from current average.
1979 dollars.
                                            E-15a

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION STUDY
                                             Appendix E
                               FOOTNOTES

     ^•"Economic  Analysis  of  Final  Section  5  Notice  Requirements,
 Appendix F:   Comparison  of  TSCA Premanufacture  Notification
 Procedures,  the Pre-Market  Procedures  under FFDCA,  and  the
 Registration Process  under  FIFRA,"  ICF Incorporated,  July, 1981.

     ^"Analysis  of TSCA Section 8(a)  Small Manufacturers Exemption,"
 ICF  Incorporated, May 1981.                                                        *'
    ^"Preserving Innovation Under  the  Toxic  Substances  Control Act,"
Chemical Manufacturers Association,  January  20,  1982, p.  26.                      ;

    ^Kline Guide to the Chemical Industry, Fourth  Edition,  Charles H.             !
Kline and Co.,  Inc., Fairfleld, N.J.,  Susan  Curry, Editor,  1980, p.               ?
46.                                                                               j
                                                                                  i
    5Id. at 66.                                                                   \

    6Id. at 67.                                                                   i
     ~~~~~                                                                          i
    ,                                                                             }
    'J.D. Riggleraan, Presidential  Address at  the 33rd Annual Meeting    »
of Northeastern Weed Science Society,  Boston, January 3,  1979.                    v

    ^Based on interviews with new  product development personnel at                i.
several major pesticide manufacturers.                                            I
                                                                                  v
    ^ These discount rates are net  of inflation.  The effect of infla-             .,'
tion has been eliminated from the  analysis by using constant dollars.             |
                                                                                  *y
    leased on interviews with new product develoment personnel at                |
several major pesticide manufacturers.                                            (
                                                                                  \
    **A pesticide formulation plant would probably be worth con*                  .-
siderably more than 40Z of original cost, because of the  ease of tran-            ]
sition from one formula to another.  We do not specifically consider              •
the case of the formulation plant  in this example.                                }

    12Teatimony on H.R. 4152 by Richard Wellman, Vice President and
General Manager, Union Carbide Company before the House Committee on
Agriculture, March 1971.
         could have alternatively assumed the manufacturer would only
receive their variable costs of producing the product as  inventory
payments.  If this were the case, the manufacturer might  be able to
sell the inventory to customers in countries that do not  recognize EPA
cancellation actions.
                                                                                   r
          Pesticide Cancellations/Suspensions;  A Survey of Economic
Impact, Office of Pesticide Programs, March 1980.
                                 E-16                                            |

-------
                                             INDEMNIFICATION  STUDY
                                             Appendix E
             on  testimony before Congress and recent conversations with
personnel  of two  major pesticide producers.

    ^Economics of  the Pesticide Industry, ICF Incorporated,  for EPA
Office of  Pesticide Programs, August 1980, page 3.
            taken  from The Biologic and Economic Assessment of Silvex.
A report of  the USDA-States-EPA Silvex RPAR team, Draft Final Report,
March 2, 1981.
                                                                                          i *'
                                  •u.s. GOVI;IINM,>T FIIINTINC OKFICM
                                  E-17

-------