United States Office of Pesticides Environmental Protection and Toxic Substances Agency Washington DC 20460 December 1983 E PA 560/4-83-003 \vEPA Indemnification Report to Congress ------- Indemnification Report to Congress by Ellen Selonick Berick Economics and Technology Division Office of Toxic Substances U.S. Environmental Protection Agency Washington, DC 20460 ------- Contents Executive Summary iii 1 Introduction 1 Assumptions and Limitations of the Study 2 Methodology 4 Outline of the Report 7 2 Factors Supporting Indemnification Decisions 9 Introduction and Legal Background 9 Availability of Alternatives 11 Equity 13 Incentive Effects 15 Impact on Behavior 16 Programs 16 Administration and Cost 17 3 Need to Expand Existing Indemnification Programs 19 Oil Spill Cleanup and Chemical Spill Cleanup 19 Innovative Waste Treatment Technology and Other Demonstration Grant Programs 21 Government Contractor's Indemnity 22 Unreasonable Clean Air Act Enforcement Action 22 Indemnification under FIFRA 23 4 Need for New Indemnification Programs 27 Confidential Business Information 28 Delays in Permit Processing 29 Regulatory Conflicts and Overlaps 30 Use of Emergency Powers 30 Unreasonable Administrative Enforcement 32 Changes in Agency Policy 33 5 Costs and Financing of Indemnification 35 Estimating the Cost 35 Impact of Indemnification 36 Financing 39 Conclusions 43 ------- Executive Summary This Report to Congress fulfills the mandate of section 25(a) of the Toxic Substances Control Act (TSCA) to de- termine whether and under what conditions the gov- ernment should indemnify any person as a result of an action taken by the Administrator of the Environmental Protection Agency. The government generally does not compensate for the cost of complying with valid regula- tions, which the Supreme Court recently said is a burden borne to secure "the advantage of living and doing busi- ness in a civilized community". Andrus v. Allard, 444 U.S. 51, 67 (1979). However, on rare occasions, Congress has awarded compensation for losses caused by agency ac- tion. The purpose of the study was to determine whether EPA causes any harms which justify indemnification. The government has traditionally been immune from almost all liability for the results of its actions. Although recent statutes have expanded potential liability, core gov- ernment functions such as policy decisions and writing budgets are still protected. Regulations represent a social agreement on an adjustment of private rights for the pub- lic welfare. More practically, the government could hardly function if it had to pay for every cost of its actions. Against this background of limited government liability, the instances of indemnification stand out as exceptions. Indemnification has distinct meanings in the law of con- tracts and equity. An equitable right of indemnity may accrue to a party who discharged a duty for which an- other is primarily responsible, for example an employee who paid his employer's debt. Or a party may agree to in- demnify another for certain kinds of losses in return for payment, as in an insurance contract. Indemnification has been used loosely to refer to a wide variety of compensa- tion situations involving the government with parallels to both equity and contract law. In addition, it is a remedy for an error by the government, and can be used to insure against certain risks, thus encouraging contractors and iii ------- other private parties to undertake risky enterprises of so- cial utility. The most recent approval of indemnification is the "Tris Bill" passed by the 97th Congress. The statute gave the U.S. Claims Court special jurisdiction to hear and award claims relating to the ban of children's sleepwear treated with the flame retardant tris. Other claims for indemnifica- tion in similar circumstances have been denied: for ex- ample, those by food packers after cyclamates were ban- ned. As a first step in determining "what conditions, if any" justify indemnification, this study examined existing in- demnification programs, both at EPA and other agencies. (The charts on pages 45, 46, and 47 summarize EPA and non-EPA indemnification for reference and compari- son). No single formula could explain why indemnifica- tion was granted in all of these cases, and no situation al- ways warranted indemnification. However, six factors appear to be important in considering indemnification re- quests: 1. Availability of Alternatives. Every environmental statute administered by EPA contains mechanisms for relief of unjustified, erroneous, or otherwise unreasonable losses due to actions by the Administrator. These mechanisms include exceptions, variances, regulatory review, phased- in compliance periods, and cost benefit analyses, among others. Indemnification is used when these alternative means of preventing, shifting, reducing, or sharing regula- tory losses will not suffice. The mechanisms are generally less effective in mitigating losses of non-regulated parties. Directly regulated parties are not as likely to be in- demnified because the administrative procedures usually provide adequate relief without requiring the government to spend money. 2. Equity. Indemnification is usually granted to "innocent" parties, those who did not contribute to their own losses. Directly regulated parties are rarely indemnified as they often share a responsibility for the loss or the failure to foresee it. Also, indemnification is more common when the government has a direct responsibility for the loss or is considered to be at fault. 3. Incentives. Indemnification is sometimes used to in- fluence the behavior of the recipients or the government itself. 4. Effects on Behavior. Care must be taken that an in- demnification program does not cause unintentional effects on behavior. For example, the availability of in- demnification could reduce incentives for private parties IV ------- to prevent loss, or might inhibit the government in taking actions that could lead to compensible losses. 5. Need for a program. Indemnification programs, as op- posed to individual or ad hoc indemnification payments, are set up in advance of a particular loss. Programs are more efficient in dealing with a number of losses, and they provide better incentives than ad hoc decisions after the loss occurs. 6. Cost, financing, and administration. These factors affect the design of a program rather than the initial decision to establish one. The study used these factors to evaluate the need for new indemnification programs at EPA. Rather than con- struct a model indemnification rule and search for situa- tions at EPA that would fit, we looked for real and hypothetical losses to evaluate for indemnification. We first considered possible expansion of the four existing in- demnification programs at EPA to analagous situations and then the need for completely new indemnification programs. Research on EPA's programs was conducted between November 1978 and May 1982, with some checks and updating early in 1983. Conclusions None of the four indemnification programs in the laws administered by EPA should be expanded at this time. The indemnification programs already established at EPA represent the variety of uses for indemnification. The pro- grams and the situations they address are all different. Each was analyzed separately and revealed a different reason why expansion is unnecessary at this time. 1) Section 311(i) of the Clean Water Act (CWA) compen- sates owners or operators of vessels or facilities from which quantities of oil or hazardous substances are discharged who clean up discharges of these substances for the cost of their efforts, if the owners or operators can show that the discharges were caused solely by acts or omissions over which they had no control. (See p. A-41 of the Back- ground Report). The promise of indemnification encour- ages prompt clean up by those close to the spill by postponing disputes over financial responsibility. Awards are made by the Court of Claims and paid out of a fund established by sec. 311(k) that is replenished by penal- ties, recovered costs, and appropriations. ------- The most natural place to contemplate expanding the oil spill provision is to spills of other substances. All re- leases of hazardous chemicals are now covered by the Comprehensive Environmental Response, Compensation, and Liability Act (CERCLA or "Superfund") which employs an approach similar to sec. 311(0 among its other pro- visions. CERCLA authorizes the government to reimburse the clean up costs of non-liable parties, provided the clean up was certified in advance by the responsible federal official and performed in accordance with the National Contingency Plan. Because CERCLA covers most of the situations to which sec. 311(i) could logically be ex- tended, there is no need for additional indemnification at this time. 2) Section 202(a)(3) of the Clean Water Act pays for repair or replacement of failed innovative and alternative tech- nology in waste water treatment plants subsidized by EPA. Very few of the plants utilizing innovative and alternative technology have been completed, accounting in part for the small number of claims made to date. (Pay- ment must be made with money that would otherwise be used for constructing plants - no separate reserve fund was authorized). There is no evidence that indemnification without the accompanying subsidy would encourage in- novation. If the government does decide to absorb the financial risks of experimental technology in any field, the purchase of commercial insurance through grant funds should be studied as an alternative to indemnification. 3) Section 113(b) of the Clean Air Act (CAA) authorizes payment of attorney's fees and court costs of parties against whom the Agency took an unreasonable enforce- ment action. Only one $10,000 claim was paid (and one other made) since enactment in 1977. In spite of multiple layers of review and a policy of concentrating on the worst violators, there is a possibility of unreasonable en- forcement actions under every statute enforced by EPA. However, new indemnification authority is not needed for this purpose because the Equal Access to Justice Act of 1980 (EAJA) provides attorney's fees and court costs whenever small businesses prevail against the gov- ernment and the position of the government was not "substantially justified". The EAJA applies to all court and formal administrative actions, not just judicial enforce- ment, thus expanding the scope of the CAA provision in some ways. VI ------- 4) Section 15 of the Federal Insecticide, Fungicide, and Rodenticide Act (FIFRA) requires compensation for in- ventories of pesticides rendered worthless by the suspen- sion and cancellation of the pesticide's registration due to imminent risk when certain statutory criteria are met. The section includes a "special rule" allowing the Administra- tor to permit a reasonable time for the use or disposal of such pesticides instead of paying indemnification. This section is one of the two found during the study in which indemnification has been provided for the consequences of a valid regulation, and the only program enacted be- fore any losses had occured. The statute did not desig- nate a method of funding. The provision has been used for three cancellations since it was enacted in 1972. Two of them resulted in small payments from EPA funds to a total of five claimants. However, the cancellation of some registrations for home and garden uses of Silvex resulted in over $18 million awarded to hundreds of retailers, distributors, for- mulators, manufacturers, and others. The Silvex claimants applied first to EPA. After EPA found the claims "appro- priate" but declared itself without funds to pay them, the claimants filed in the U.S. Claims Court. TSCA is the obvious statute to examine for expansion of the FIFRA program because it is the only other EPA- administered statute that authorizes product bans. There is no evidence that bans of chemicals under TSCA will cause losses beyond the ordinary costs of compliance. Nor is there any other reason that chemical bans should be treated differently from bans of food additives, drugs, or other products under other statutes. TSCA contains authority to order the manufacturer of a banned chemical to repurchase it from processors and us- ers even in an imminent hazard situation. The repurchase provision would compensate many of those who could not be expected to anticipate the ban, and who have less responsibility for the safety of the chemical, such as con- sumers or formulators. Repurchase orders would also en- courage compliance with a ban and disposal order, an argument made for the FIFRA indemnification program. TSCA affirms the responsibility of chemical man- ufacturers and processors for the continued safety of their products. Thus, indemnification could not be justified by equity arguments based on the Agency's responsibility for evaluating hazardous chemicals. Any individual inequities or errors that might occur under TSCA are difficult to foresee and impossible to plan for under one indemnifica- tion program. It is more appropriate to use existing in- demnification mechanisms, such as private bills, until there is evidence of a need for a comprehensive program. VII ------- There is no evidence of current need for any new indemnification programs at EPA. The final step in the study was to search alt of the laws and regulations administered by EPA to find any poten- tially indemnifiable losses. Six categories of actions that seemed more likely to result in such losses helped focus the search. In addition to reviewing all the major laws and regulations and talking to many EPA officals, we con- sulted trade associations and individual companies. While these conversations did not amount to a formal survey, they were extensive. We gathered from the conversations that the primary interest of industry is preventing regula- tory losses by changing statutes and regulations rather than obtaining compensation for losses after they occur. Summary conclusions for the six primary categories of potentially indemnifiable losses follow. Disclosure of confidential business information. The potential for either authorized or unauthorized disclosure causes concern to all who must report confidential in- formation to EPA. Preventing accidental releases by secur- ity procedures and monitoring, reducing unauthorized re- lease by administrative discipline, and reducing the num- ber of authorized releases by statutory amendment all appear to present more effective solutions to the problem than indemnification. In addition, there are severe ad- ministrative problems in calculating the value of the loss of confidentiality of different kinds of information. Further- more, handling confidential information is a government- wide function, and if a remedy is needed, it should be one that is applicable to all agencies. Delay in issuing permits. Closer examination of this com- mon complaint revealed that delays in EPA permits are not significant. Both EPA and industry have in the past fo- cused on ways to speed up the process, and there is no current industry interest in indemnification. Furthermore, there would be considerable administrative problems in separating the contribution of the Agency from other fac- tors. Even if the Agency took longer than usual to review a permit, it might be because the application was de- ficient or the decision complicated. If the Agency had to adhere to a schedule or risk paying indemnification, it might make poor decisions in hard cases and fail to in- volve all necessary parties (including states) for fear of delay. Conflicting and overlapping requirements. Neither a re- cent GAO report nor our search found very many con- flicting or overlapping regulations. One reason is that VIII ------- most of the statutes administered by EPA contain pro- visions for coordination with other EPA offices and other agencies. In addition, multiple opportunities for formal and informal review and concurrence prevent conflicting regulations. Emergency actions. Actions taken in emergency situations pose a greater risk of inequity and error because there are fewer opportunities for the regulated parties to challenge the action and less time to consider exemptions or var- iances. However, an indemnification program that would cover all future emergencies would be too broad and vague to help make individual decisions. Unreasonable administrative enforcement. Indemnifica- tion for unreasonable enforcement under the Clean Air Act applies only to judicial enforcement, but indemnifica- tion does not appear necessary for administrative enforce- ment actions at this time because there are adequate alternatives. The Equal Access to Justice Act (EAJA) pro- vides attorney fees and court costs for small businesses and individuals who prevail against the government un- less the position of the government is substantially jus- tified. The EAJA covers those presumably most vulner- able to an unreasonable enforcement action. If the EAJA is not sufficient, another approach would be to ensure availability of judicial review before enforcement where review is not already available. Changes in agency policy. Changes in agency policy re- quire the same protection as the original government policy decisions so that the agencies may respond objec- tively and effectively to changes in circumstances. Ad- ministrative law provides ways to influence and review changes which do not require courts to pass judgment on the policy decisions of another branch of government. Furthermore, there are many alternatives to indemnifica- tion that can prevent or reduce losses incident to changes in policy. Many potentially indemnifiable losses can be handled through established procedures and will not require new indemnification programs. There are established mechanisms through which Con- gress can grant extraordinary relief including indemnifica- tion. One is private legislation, a bill of specific rather than general application. Another is a grant of special * jurisdiction to the U.S. Claims Court to hear and award IX ------- claims which would otherwise be precluded by law. Such procedures allow Congress to make special exceptions for political or equitable reasons without adding a permanent federal responsibility or establishing a new legal principle. This appears to be the appropriate response, as many of the losses and potential losses are themselves exceptions resulting from unusual circumstances of an individual case rather than the normal workings of an EPA statute or program. The factors identified in this analysis will help to make decisions on whether particular incidents should be in- demnified and whether an individual response will suffice or a program is needed. Ultimately, the decision to in- demnify for regulatory losses is a political one which, by its nature as a safety valve in a democratic system and an exception from general legal principles, cannot be re- duced to a formula. ------- Introduction Congress included in the Toxic Substances Control Act of 1976 (TSCA) a requirement that the Administrator de- termine whether EPA ought to indemnify those to whom it causes loss. This report is submitted in fulfillment of the mandate of TSCA sec. 25(a) which provides: INDEMNIFICATION STUDY — The Administrator shall conduct a study of all Federal laws administered by the Administrator for the purpose of determining whether and under what conditions, if any, indemnification should be accorded any person as a result of any action taken by the Administrator under any such law. The study shall - (1) include an estimate of the probable cost of any in- demnification programs which may be recommended; (2) include an examination of all viable means of financing the cost of any recommended indemnification; and (3) be completed and submitted to Congress within two years from the effective date of enactment of this Act. The General Accounting Office shall review the ade- quacy of the study submitted to Congress pursuant to paragraph (3) and shall report the results of this review to the Congress within six months of the date such study is submitted to Congress. ------- Assumptions and Limitations of the Study In a recent opinion denying compensation for the loss in value of property due to regulatory restrictions, the Su- preme Court said that the cost of regulation is a burden borne to secure "the advantage of living and doing busi- ness in a civilized community". Andrus v. A/lard, 444 U.S. 51, 67 (1979). While this is the dominant attitude toward the costs government imposes on the public, from time to time Congress has awarded compensation. The objective of this study was to determine whether EPA causes harm for which the government should pay. There are no pat- terns of loss or potential loss that justify a new in- demnification program at this time. The study mandate provided no guidance on what might justify indemnification; it did not even define the term. The first task of the study, therefore, was to define the terms and decide upon the scope of consideration. The common legal use of the term indemnification was helpful as an analogy. Indemnification between private parties generally occurs when one party agrees to assume the liability of another (as in an insurance contract) or be- cause one party is legally responsible for claims paid by another (an employer for certain liabilities of an employee incurred within the scope of his employment). Indemnification has been used by the government both when it is responsible for the loss and when it agrees to assume the financial responsibility for other reasons. The government has agreed to assume certain liabilities associated with international exhibits of art and artifacts for private museums, though, of course, it has not con- tributed to the risks of fire, theft or damage. The in- demnification program is unlike private insurance because the museums do not pay premiums for this coverage. In some other cases the government has indemnified parties for the consequences of a mistake that the government made, such as erroneously declaring that a crop of spi- nach was contaminated with a pesticide. The most recent indemnification program was the "Tris Bill", enacted at the end of the 97th Congress. The law gives the U.S. Claims Court special jurisdiction to hear and award claims for the value of children's sleepwear which was rendered worthless when the Consumer Product Safety Commis- sion declared tris-treated sleepwear a banned hazardous substance. It appears that the implementation of the ban concentrated the effects on a relatively small segment of the industry. (See Background Report p. A-22) ------- The pesticide indemnification program that was the original impetus for this study is oddly unrepresentative of other indemnification programs. It is the only program that was established in anticipation of loss, before any losses actually occurred, and it is one of just two pro- grams that indemnify for the cost of complying with a valid regulation. The 1972 amendments to the Federal In- secticide, Rodenticide, and Fungicide Act (FIFRA) included a section requiring EPA to indemnify owners of pesticides for the value of the stocks when EPA suspended and then cancelled the registration without allowing the owners to sell their inventory. Some members of Congress who were displeased with the amendment to FIFRA (now sec- tion 15) tried to repeal it by inserting language to that effect into a precursor of TSCA the following year. While TSCA was under consideration, the section evolved into the study included in section 25(a) of TSCA. The definition of indemnification adopted for this report after consideration of these and other examples and the language of the mandate is: compensation by the U.S. government to those injured by government action under the laws administered by EPA. It is important to dis- tinguish indemnification from the other payments made by EPA. These include payment for goods and services, subsidies such as those to build local sewage treatment plants, and disaster relief. None of these payments is for loss resulting from agency action. Several limitations on the scope of inquiry are related to the definition. Compensation for the victims of environ- mental disasters is outside the scope of study, because such losses generally do not result from an action or deci- sion not to act by the Administrator. The disaster relief sometimes granted when a tragedy strikes an entire com- munity results from a philanthropic impulse rather than law, equity or economic efficiency. Actions under the major environmental laws were examined, but actions under various other laws admin- istered by EPA concerning contracts, civil rights, and employment were not. The direct impacts of actions or decisions not to take action were considered, but the in- direct effects were not. For example, a ban on a particular pesticide would directly affect both the manufacturer of the pesticide and the farmers who use it, but would only indirectly affect the consumers of farm products. One important limitation was acceptance of current legal authority as given. For example, a potential problem at EPA might theoretically be solved by amending the Federal Tort Claims Act. Evaluating such a suggestion is beyond the scope of this report, as it would entail weighing the impact of such a change on the entire gov- ernment, not just the EPA. ------- The report distinguishes between ad hoc indemnifica- tion payments and indemnification programs and con- centrates on the latter. Ad hoc, or individual payments, are made in response to a claim arising from a particular situation, generally without a prior determination that in- demnification would be appropriate in that situation. In- demnification programs are established in advance of a particular loss to cover a category of events. They are a more efficient response to a series or cluster of similar losses, and they can be used to influence the behavior of those who desire to obtain indemnification later. The leg- islative history of TSCA indicated that indemnification programs were the prime concern as they are explicit and permanent expressions of policy. Methodology Phase One This Report to Congress is based upon a contractor's study, referred to as the Background Report, which is in- cluded as an attachment. (Page numbers in parentheses refer to the contractor's Background Report unless other- wise labeled.) The Background Report was prepared under contract with close guidance and review by EPA. Phase I of the study was a review of public and private legislation in which indemnification had been granted in the past. It also included a legislative history of section 25(a) of TSCA, and section 15 of the Federal Insecticide, Fungicide, and Rodenticide Act (FIFRA) to help define the language of the study mandate. More generally, there was a review of government compensation policies such as the Fifth Amendment to the Constitution, legislative ex- ceptions to sovereign immunity (especially the Federal Tort Claims Act), and a survey of current legislative issues including regulatory reform, regulatory relief, and com- pensation for asbestos workers and government con- tractors. A summary of the most relevant legal analysis is contained in Appendix A of the Background Report. Five factors that seem to have been important to Con- gress in past decisions were identified. They were con- tinually refined and elaborated as their application be- came better understood. Availability of alternatives. Indemnification is used when there are no alternative means of preventing, shifting, reducing, or sharing regulatory losses. Directly regulated parties are less likely to be indemnified because the reg- ulatory relationship often provides alternatives to in- demnification that do not require financial expenditures. ------- Equity. Indemnification is usually granted to "innocent" parties, those who did not contribute to their own loss. Directly regulated parties are rarely indemnified as they usually share a responsibility for the loss or the failure to foresee it. Also, indemnification is more common when the government has a direct responsibility for the loss or is considered to be at fault. Incentives. Indemnification is sometimes used to in- fluence the behavior of the recipients, or the government itself, but care must be taken to avoid unintended side- effects on the behavior of the agency or the indemnified parties. Need for a program. Indemnification programs, as op- posed to individual or Ad hoc payments, are established in advance of a particular loss. Programs are more effi- cient in dealing with a number of similar losses and they can provide incentives. Cost/financing, and administration. These factors affect the design of the specific program rather than a threshold determination of whether indemnification is justified. Phase TWO During Phase II of the Background study, four in- demnification programs were identified in the laws ad- ministered by EPA. These are: • Sec. 311(i) of the Clean Water Act (cleanup costs for certain oil spills); • Sec. 202(a)(3) of the Clean Water Act (payment for re- pair or replacement of innovative and alternative technol- ogy in waste water treatment facilities); • Sec. 113(b) of the Clean Air Act (reimbursement of attorney's fees and court costs for unreasonable enforce- ment actions); and • Sec. 15 of FIFRA (compensation for loss of inventory due to emergency suspension and cancellation of pesti- cide registrations). The legislative goals and major issues of the legislative debate for each of the four were ascertained. Then inter- views and research explored how the programs have worked, whether the debate was accurate in its considera- tion of advantages and problems with indemnification, and whether the existing programs should be modified. The resulting detailed descriptions of the EPA programs comprise Section III of the Background Report. ------- Phase Three Based on the information gained from prior work, Phase III reviewed all major EPA programs to determine whether there have been or might be instances in which in- demnification was or would be appropriate. First, situa- tions analagous to existing programs were evaluated, then entirely new situations were considered. Industry complaints about environmental regulation and adminis- trative enforcement, rulemaking comments, and dis- cussions with EPA officials and outside experts were ex- amined for patterns of loss that might justify indemnifica- tion. To focus the search, six categories of potential los- ses were defined as those most likely to contain in- demnifiable losses. In addition to being concerns of reg- ulated industry, they presented many of the factors earlier identified as supporting decisions to indemnify. The six categories are: • disclosure of confidential business information; • delays in issuing permits; • conflicting and overlapping regulatory requirements; • emergency actions; • unreasonable administrative enforcement; and • changes in policy. All major EPA programs were screened for possible los- ses, with particular attention to those in the above cate- gories. Then real, potential, and hypothetical losses were analyzed by applying the factors which are discussed in more detail below. Most indemnification has been granted in response to an industry appeal for it; so it was important to determine current industry attitudes. Major trade associations were consulted for knowledge of partic- ular incidents for which indemnification might be appro- priate, and for their opinions on the desirability of in- demnification in general. Trade association representa- tives often referred us to specific industry contacts. In addition, some industry representatives were called to discuss specific issues or incidents involving their in- dustry. A few environmental organizations, ex-EPA offic- als and congressional staff were also consulted. Although there were many informal discussions, they did not amount to a formal survey. The list of organizations con- tacted is provided as Appendix C of the Background Re- port. The investigation of past and existing indemnification programs included information on their cost and details of the financing. Section 25(a) of TSCA required this study to include an estimate of the probable cost of any in- demnification programs which may be recommended. ------- Therefore, efforts were made to develop a method of es- timating the cost of indemnification programs, should it be decided to recommend a program. The indirect im- pacts of indemnification as well as the direct costs were considered. The statute also requested an examination of all viable means of financing any recommended pro- grams. Building upon the information gathered about past programs, a full range of alternative financing mechan- isms was explored. Because the report does not recommend establishing a new indemnification program, there is no specific estimate of cost or financing. How- ever, the results of the general analysis are contained in the Background Report (Appendix D: Indemnification Financing Systems and Appendix E: Costs and Impacts of Indemnification). This Report to Congress was prepared by EPA primarily from the information and analysis in the Background Re- port prepared by the contractors and is the official Agency response to the TSCA mandate. Outline of the Report Section 2 of the report discusses factors that seem to have been important to indemnification decisions in the past, and how these factors can help make similar de- cisions in the future. Section 3 describes the existing programs at EPA and the reasons for not recommending expansion of any of them. Section 4 evaluates the six most likely loss categories and explains why no new indemnification programs are needed to respond to them at this time. Section 5 discusses the problems of estimating costs of indemnification programs, the possible impacts of the costs on recipients and the agency, the range of options for funding indemnification programs, and some con- siderations in choosing a particular method. Section 6 contains conclusions and questions for furth- er study. ------- Factors Supporting Indemnification Decisions Introduction and Legal Background Compensation for the consequences of government ac- tion has historically been rare, and remains an exception. Sovereign immunity was an important principle in the re- lationship between the U.S. government and its citizens: the government could not be sued without its consent or otherwise held liable for the consequences of its policy or the actions of its employees. The Fifth Amendment to the Constitution contains one of the few original exceptions to sovereign immunity. It requires the government to pay compensation when it takes private property for public use. Until the middle of this century, if a citizen was in- jured in any other way, virtually his only recourse was to ask Congress for a private bill of relief. For equitable and practical reasons, Congress has cre- ated standard procedures for granting compensation for many of the claims previously brought to Congress as pri- vate legislation. The Federal Tort Claims Act (FTCA, 28 U.S.C. sec. 1346{b); 28 U.S.C. sec. 2671) is a broad au- thorization for injured parties to sue the government for damage caused by negligent government employees acting in the scope of their employment. Most suits under the FTCA have nothing to do with regulation. They con- cern negligence in the operation of government vehicles or air traffic control towers, for example. The Tucker Act is another broad waiver of sovereign immunity. It con- ferred jurisdiction on the Court of Claims to hear cases founded on the Constitution, statutes, regulations, and contracts, including most money claims except pensions and those founded on tort. The core governmental activities continue to be pro- tected from suit. The Supreme Court explained one of the reasons in a recent case: government regulation—by definition—involves the adjustment 06 rights for the public good. Often this adjustment curtails some potential for the use or ------- economic exploitation of private property. To re- quire compensation in all such circumstances would effectively compel the government to regulate by purchase. Andrus v. Allard, 444 U.S. 51 (1979)) at 65, emphasis in original) While there is some controversy over what should be included in the protected core, there is general agreement that judges should not interfere in the policy-making of the executive branch. The objective legal standards usual- ly used to evaluate the facts of a tort case can not be used to judge the wisdom or political expediency of policy de- cisions. The line of cases interpreting one of the exceptions to the FTCA waiver of immunity balances the need to protect core government activity and a desire to make equitable relief more broadly available. The exception says that the government may not be sued for damages resulting from a "discretionary function". The courts have steadily re- duced the number of activities regarded as "discretion- ary". Execution or implementation of most policies are now considered operational, even when professional judgment must be exercised; for example, in the audit of a federal credit union or inspection of a batch of polio vaccine. However, policy decisions such as setting stan- dards or budget priorities are still clearly discretionary, and thus protected from tort liability. The line of cases interpreting the Fifth Amendment re- quirement to pay for "takings" also shows a protection of regulatory decisions. The regulation of property, even regulation severely affecting its value, is generally not considered to be a taking. Actual title must be transferred, or almost all of the benefits of ownership removed for a compensible taking to be found. Property which is a pub- lic nuisance, causing a threat to public health or safety, has always been considered within the power of the gov- ernment to eliminate without compensation. One result of the general expansion of the statutes waiving sovereign immunity is a reduction in the number of private bills. The statutes waiving sovereign immunity authorize suits against the government for many of the claims that formerly could only be made to Congress. Now that torts by government employees and breaches of contract by the government can be the basis of court ac- tions, the majority of the remaining private bills are peti- tions for relief from immigration restrictions. However, a few private bills have granted indemnification for losses caused by regulatory activity. (See Background Report p. A-12). This background discussion of legal history and princi- ples is important to the study in several ways. It identifies 10 ------- situations in which compensation is already available, making indemnification redundant. It also provides guide- lines for decisions in other situations in which in- demnification may be appropriate. The legal principles de- veloped in years of statutory and case law are the only objective measure available. This study could not simulta- neously evaluate the criteria for judgment and the in- cidents themselves. The fact that indemnification is an exception to some basic and longstanding principles of law means that cir- cumstances must justify making each exception. There is no formula, mathematical or legal, that can predict which circumstances will justify indemnification, but our analysis of past programs has resulted in factors that clarify the decisions. The most important are the existence of alternative ways of mitigating the loss and whether in- demnification would be equitable. This section will ex- plain and illustrate the following factors: • Availability of alternatives, • Equity, • Incentives, • Impact on behavior, • Need for a program, and • Cost, financing and administration. Summary charts of EPA and non-EPA indemnification programs at pages 45, 46, and 47 provide descriptions of the indemnification programs mentioned in the following discussion as examples. Availability of Alternatives There are numerous ways that losses potentially ad- dressed by indemnification can be avoided, shifted, spread or the impact otherwise reduced. (See Background Report Appendix B). Indemnification as a relief mech- anism is quite rare in federal statutes, but the alternatives to indemnification are commonly used. Examination of the statutes administered by EPA clearly demonstrates that Congress has taken potential losses seriously, and has attempted to prevent or respond to nearly every one by some alternative. The instances of loss avoidance are frequent; even primary statutory objectives are at times compromised to prevent losses. Indemnification seems to be a measure of last resort when compromise with the 11 ------- Agency's mission is impossible and no other alternatives are available. Legislative and administrative alternatives, such as granting waivers, public participation in agency decision- making and postponing regulatory deadlines often do not work if those suffering the losses are not regulated by the agency or if the agency's range of action is very limited. When the government is not responsible for the action causing the loss, it can not prevent it. For example, the government could not prevent cattle from contracting brucellosis, nor could it endanger the public health by waiving the prohibition on selling such animals for con- sumption. Granting an extension of time or allowing participation or review of the inspector's decision will not reduce the loss. Similarly, the risks for which defense con- tractors, NASA contractors, some Superfund clean up contractors, and museums request indemnification are beyond the ability of the government to prevent. The risks to the contractors and museums result from the inherent hazards of what they are doing, and the right of third par- ties to sue them under contract or tort law for the con- sequences. The agency cannot change the tort or contract law, or reduce the hazards of cleaning up chemical waste sites (except by providing good advice); it can only decide to absorb some of the financial risks itself. When the loss is caused by Agency action, there are generally alternatives other than payment of compensa- tion available to prevent or reduce the loss. For example, many product bans are phased in, rather than made im- mediately effective. The ban on use of chlorofluorocar- bons for aerosol propellants is one example, and many of the pesticides bans are handled this way too. The transi- tion prevents owners and distributors of the product from being caught with inventories that they cannot sell. It also gives the processors and users time to find substitutes. Depending upon the product and its dangers, "disposal by use" may actually be less risky than collecting a large quantity in one place to bury or burn. Although the administrative alternatives of participation and review, waivers, exceptions and postponement of deadlines can reduce many inequities and prevent many errors for regulated parties, there are occasions when these mechanisms are not available. Emergency action forecloses many administrative options. Thus, it is not surprising that several of the examples of indemnification result from emergency action. The Mizokami Brothers spi- nach growers lost most of a harvest before they could successfully prove that the FDA's determination that their spinach was contaminated with heptachlor was erroneous. (Background Report p. A-20). 12 ------- Other alternatives involve spreading the loss among other private parties either through insurance, restoration funds (such as Superfund), or through the market (so that those who benefit from the product share in the full cost). The cost of regulation generally can and should be inter- nalized and passed on in prices. One reason for in- demnification is the complete absence of ways to share the cost. Another alternative to indemnification is provided by existing procedures for private bills in Congress. Histor- ically, private bills have been used to provide relief when jurisdictional barriers or other factors prevented use of the court system. Thus, they have constituted a safety valve for exceptional cases. There are three types of private legislation presently used by Congress. All can provide relief from the strictures of sovereign immunity in exceptional circumstances. The largest category consists of private bills handled en- tirely by the legislature, and funded by special appropria- tions. Congress enlists the help of the U.S. Claims Court for the other two categories of private bills. Congressional reference cases are referred to the Commissioners of the Claims Court for hearings, findings and a recommenda- tion to Congress. The cases are later transferred back to the legislative body for final decision, and for special appropriations if a claim is awarded. The Marlin Toy case was a congressional reference. Bills of special jurisdiction provide relief indirectly by lifting a procedural barrier. Special jurisdiction is conferred upon the Claims Court for that case only, and it then makes a final decision. Judg- ment, if any, is paid out of the Court's Judgment Fund. The Mizokami Brothers spinach case (Background report p. A-20) was a private bill of special jurisdiction. Equity The most common argument for an indemnification pay- ment or program is that equity requires the government to make a payment. The equity of a situation is rarely clear; usually there is fault and merit on both sides. It is impossible to evaluate equitable factors in advance of an actual loss, because they depend so heavily upon the par- ticular facts of a situation. It is helpful to breakdown the broad category of "equity" into four more specific in- quiries concerning: procedural inequity, substantive in- equity, fault of the government, and contributing fault of the party claiming indemnification. Each of these is ex- amined below. 13 ------- Procedural Inequity This factor is the easiest to evaluate. Denial of a hearing or insufficient notice are usually obvious. The relief for a procedural inequity is more often to repeat the procedure than to pay compensation. Procedural inequity is a fre- quent argument in challenges to agency regulations and enforcement actions, for example. If a court agrees, it usually requires the agency to re-propose the regulation or drop the enforcement action. Statutes governing con- tracts with the government provide some relief for pro- cedural mistakes or inequities in contractual situations. Substantive Inequity Substantive inequity is a more elusive concept. In the indemnification context, substantive inequity often refers to a situation in which one party absorbs more than its share of the cost of a socially beneficial action. For ex- ample, the ban of children's sleepwear containing tris be- nefited all children who would otherwise have worn tris- treated pajamas and risked developing cancer. However, due to the provisions of the law, and the way the ban was written, a small part of the commercial network that pro- duced the sleepwear absorbed a large proportion of the total cost of the ban. (Background Report p. A-22). The law's repurchase provision required clothing manu- facturers to purchase inventory from the retailers and the distributors. However, the ban did not extend to fabric or the yarn, and thus the clothing manufacturers could not resell their (augmented) inventory to anyone further up the manufacturing chain. The clothing manufacturers are relatively small firms who merely purchased cloth treated with the harmful chemical, and could not reason- ably be expected to foresee the hazards of the chemical or the possibility of government action. In contrast, all but one of the tris manufacturers, which had primary respon- sibility for the safety of their product, had ceased man- ufacture before the ban. Substantive inequities are not necessarily the fault of the government, they often have more to do with the market situation or the hazards to which the government is responding. Fault of Government Another important factor in deciding whether the gov- ernment should pay indemnity is whether the government caused the loss. The case for indemnification is naturally stronger when the government is responsible. Errors are the most obvious example of this. The government agen- cies which caused the losses supported private legislation for the Marlin Toy Co. and the Mizokami Brothers. 14 ------- Contributing Fault of Claimant Of all the equitable factors, perhaps the most useful is whether the party requesting indemnification has contrib- uted to his own loss. Every existing indemnification pro- gram denies indemnification to those who have been negligent or otherwise contributed to their own loss. A person who caused an oil spill is obligated to clean it up and is not entitled to reimbursement. (Background Report p. 78). if a farmer's negligent or illegal use of a pesticide results in contamination of his cows' milk, he is not eligi- ble for indemnification when the milk is destroyed. (Back- ground Report p. A-19). The questions of equity rarely have clear answers, and a careful investigation of the facts is needed to determine what would be equitable in each situation. Incentive Effects Indemnification and the promise of indemnification has been used to encourage certain actions by private parties. One clear example is the contractor who would not other- wise agree to perform work that the government needs done. Other parties, not under contract to the gov- ernment, can also be influenced by the provision of in- demnification to reduce certain risks. The innocent dis- chargers of oil clean it up more quickly because they know they will be reimbursed for the clean up. Congress and the State Department regard international exchanges of art as beneficial to international relations, but many museums would not be able to afford commercial in- surance on foreign art exhibits without the art and arti- facts indemnity program. (Background Report p. A-25) There is some evidence that indemnification is also used by Congress as a disincentive, to discourage an agency from taking actions with which Congress dis- agrees. Two of the EPA programs seem to be partially in- tended to affect EPA officials. The Clean Air Act provision, in addition to redressing an inequity of unreasonable en- forcement, reinforces the Agency's care to avoid "unrea- sonable" enforcement actions. The FIFRA program poses direct choice: either the Administrator must allow a rea- sonable time for use of a pesticide after cancellation of its registration, or he must provide indemnification. The de- terrent effect of both programs is muted by the fact that the indemnification payments may not come out of the Agency's budget. The use of indemnification to prevent operational errors should be and appears to have been minimal. Since mis- takes are randomly made by individuals who have other 15 ------- reasons to avoid them, the fact that the agency or gov- ernment would have to pay for a mistake would probably not prevent their occurrence. Impact on Behavior In addition to the intentional effects of indemnification it can cause unintended side-effects. The existence and severity of such side-effects on the behavior both of pri- vate parties and the agency should be evaluated as a fac- tor in the decision whether to grant indemnification. One potential effect on the behavior of regulated parties is sometimes referred to as "moral hazard". The promise of indemnification might reduce the self-regulation of pri- vate parties. For example, some feared (though there is no evidence that it has yet occurred) that the pesticide manufacturers would continue to make products they have reason to suspect will be regulated, rather than test them and perhaps voluntarily withdraw the product. There is no compensation for the loss of inventory in- venjory excluded from the market by emergency suspen- sion and cancellation. If an indemnification program is not intended to be a disincentive to the Agency, it must be carefully designed to avoid unintended disincentives. The prospect of having to pay money for the result of an action might well hinder an agency's response to a problem. Programs Once a decision has been made to provide indemnifica- tion in a particular situation, it is relatively easy to decide whether a program is needed or a single payment will suffice. Clearly it is more efficient to deal with a cluster or series of losses generically rather than individually. Sever- al of the indemnification programs began as individual payments, and evolved into broad programs later. The Federal Tort Claims Act was the result of Congress being overwhelmed by the number of private bills for negligent behavior of government employees. The FTCA allows citizens to sue the government as they would any other person (with certain limitations). The Arts and Artifacts In- demnification Act followed two private bills to indemnify museums for two particular foreign exhibits. (Background Report A-25). 16 ------- The other advantage of a program is that It can act as an incentive. Because those who might benefit will know about the program in advance, and are more certain of obtaining indemnification, it will be more likely to in- fluence them. The mere possibility of pursuading Con- gress to pass a private bill after a loss has occured will not encourage risk taking. Several of the EPA programs are designed as incentives. The CWA 311(0 oil spill in- demnification provision encourages parties to clean up immediately rather than argue about responsibility be- cause the government will pay for the cost of clean-up if the party did not cause the spill. Administration and Cost Although there are some potentially severe administrative problems in implementing indemnification programs, and the costs can be very high, it does not appear that either administrative or cost factors are absolute barriers to esta- blishing programs. There are different administrative problems associated with the different bodies that might make indemnification decisions. Congress would be a suitable body for de- cisions that are unpredictable and unique, particularly those that are difficult to settle by traditional concepts of fault and equity. Congress is not a suitable decision- making body if consistency is important, or if numerous similar claims are expected. On the other hand, the courts can provide consistency so long as the dispute concerns facts or the applications of law. Courts are neither equipped nor expected to decide matters of pure policy. Administrative agencies can often make decisions faster than either a court or the Congress. However, if the agen- cy is the same one responsible in some way for the loss, there might be a conflict in having it decide the in- demnification claim. There almost certainly would be a lack of staff having the skills and the resources to decide such questions. A separate specialized administrative agency could be established to handle indemnification claims, but there would have to be a great many claims to make it worth while. In addition, there are the common problems of conflicts between the amount of information needed to protect against fraud, and stifling the claims by too great a de- mand for documentation. Further, there is great difficulty in valuing some of the losses, particularly release of con- fidential information. 17 ------- As discussed in more detail in section 5, there are many ways of limiting the costs of indemnification pro- grams. One disadvantage is that too great a limitation would provide insufficient compensation, thus under- mining the purpose of the indemnification program. 18 ------- Need to Expand Existing Indemnification Programs In considering whether any new indemnification pro- grams are needed for EPA, it seemed logical to begin with possible extensions of the existing programs. Congress had decided that the programs were justified, and the concrete details of an existing program are easier to an- alyze than the vague details of a hypothetical one. The re- sults of the research into the existing programs, the search for analogous situations into which they might be expanded, and the evaluation of the expansion are con- tained in this section. Each situation is different, but for a variety of reasons, no expansion of the existing programs appear necessary at this time. The conclusion is bolstered by our conversations with representatives of industry and the fact that none of them recommended expansion of these programs. Oil and Chemical Spill Cleanup One incentive program at EPA is section 311(5) of the Clean Water Act. (Background Report p. 78) This section restricts one-time or episodic discharges of oil and hazardous substances, both accidental and intentional, that are not susceptible to regulation by permit. The stat- ute requires immediate notification when a spill occurs, and imposes strict liability on the discharger for the cost of clean-up. If the discharger is able to assert one of the few defenses allowed (that the discharge was caused solely by an act of God, an act of war, negligence of the United States Government, or an act or omission of a third party) he is not required to pay for clean up. If he has already done so, he is entitled to reimbursement. The indemnification provision encourages prompt action by 19 ------- the party In the best position to know of the spill rather than waiting until after the questions of liability and causation have been decided. Claims are made in the U.S. Claims Court, with settle- ment payments or awards made out of the fund es- tablished by 311(k), from appropriations, penalties, and recovered costs. Between 1973 and 1981, 45 cases were brought all involving oil spills, and totalling $6.3 million. The average payment has been $39,000 for those not dis- missed by the court. (Background Report p. 84) Although 311(i) has only been used for oil spills, it could also be used for chemicals if funds were available. (Background Report p. 79) Chemical The Comprehensive Environmental Response Liability and Spills Compensation Act of 1980 (CERCLA) covers virtually every type of hazardous substance release. Although the pri- mary approach of the Superfund law is to hold the party responsible for the release liable for remedial costs, there is also a provision similar to 311(i). This section of Super- fund authorizes the government to reimburse the clean up costs of non-liable parties, provided the clean up had been certified in advance by federal officials and was in accordance with the national contingency plan. The dif- ference in approach is due to the extreme hazard of the substances covered by Superfund, and the possibility that an inexperienced person would aggravate rather than alleviate the dangers posed by the release. Furthermore, the government must ensure that the CERCLA funds are spent on the priorities it has identified which would not be possible if there were no control over the spending of private parties. CERCLA and 311(i) address releases of hazardous sub- stitutes analogous to oil spills. Until there is evidence that these provisions are inadequate, no additional in- demnification is needed. 20 ------- Innovative Waste Treatment Technology and Other Demon stration Grant Programs Section 202 of the Clean Water Act is the other incentive indemnification program connected with water pollution. (Background Report p. 53) It gives EPA the discretion to provide indemnification to owners of wastewater treat- ment plants to repair or replace failed innovative or alternative technologies. Most of the plants built under this grant program have not begun operations, thus it is not surprising that there have been few requests for in- demnification. At least one claim has been paid: approx- imately $30,000 to replace several experimental sensors. The money for the indemnification comes from the same fund that pays for the initial construction of plants. There is no guarantee that there will be a sufficient amount for indemnification when claims are made in the future. Fur- thermore, each indemnification payment reduces the amount a state can spend on new construction, making them reluctant to authorize truly experimental technology with a high chance of failure. The increased amount of subsidy received from the federal government for inno- vative technology is probably a more powerful incentive. Other Demonstration Grant Programs The incentive provided by indemnification against failures of innovative and alternative technology in wastewater treatment plants does have theoretical application in other EPA programs. For several reasons, it does not appear to be currently needed. One of the few other demonstration grant programs is a limited one under the Clean Air Act, which supports de- velopment of innovative pollution control technology. Grants under this program help private businesses not otherwise subsidized by EPA to demonstrate a new pollu- tion control device in an industrial setting. Frequently these are "end of the pipe" devices that can simply be re- moved if they do not work. However, some devices re- quire alteration of production processes which threaten a plant in the event of failure of the pollution device. In one such case, EPA purchased commercial insurance for the host source for a new type of burner and related equip- ment in a demonstration contract at Utah Power & Light Co. (Background Report p. 62) If it were anticipated that there were going to be a number of air pollution demon- strations in which the host source would demand protec- tion from EPA, EPA should examine the relative cost to the government of purchasing commercial insurance or providing indemnification. 21 ------- Government Contractors' Indemnity EPA has a minor example of indemnification provided for government contractors doing unavoidably hazardous work. (Background Report A-26) Several of the contractors hired to clean up abandoned waste sites under Superfund demanded indemnification against liability claims by third parties. They were concerned about their liability to those living near the sites for any real or alleged contamination resulting from the cleanup. Commercial insurance would have cost as much as $300,000-$400,000 per year for $10- 25 million of coverage. The Anti-Deficiency Act prevents executive branch offi- cials from promising to pay contingent and uncertain sums or any money not specifically authorized for the purpose. Thus, a clause in the contract agreeing to in- demnify against third party claims would have been ille- gal, even if EPA had wanted to do it. To avoid the prob- lems, EPA requires the contractors to purchase one mil- lion dollars in insurance, which it pays for through the contract. For liability in excess of one million, EPA agreed to indemnify the contractor if funds are available at the time a claim is made, with no commitment to seek funds for the purpose. Apparently this was sufficient to satisfy the contractors. Any effort to expand indemnification for EPA con- tractors should be coordinated with the task force led by NASA and the Office of Federal Procurement Policy, which is considering the problem in government-wide context. (Background Report p. A-26) Therefore, no in- demnification program for EPA contractors is recom- mended. Unreasonable Clean Air Act Enforcement Action Section 113 of the Clean Air Act allows an award of court costs and attorney fees when the court finds that EPA's enforcement action was "unreasonable". (Background Re- port p. 66} Only one payment has been made and no others even requested since enactment in 1977. A manu- facturer of explosives in Arizona had been in violation of Arizona law and a negotiated compliance plan for some time when EPA initiated a suit to require compliance and recovery civil penalties. During the consideration of a pre- 22 ------- trial motion, attorneys at the Department of Justice found that EPA had not approved the State regulation as part of the State Implementation Plan, and therefore had no jurisdiction to sue. The DOJ filed a Confession of Error and agreed to pay costs and counsel fees totaling $10,000. One explanation for the paucity of awards is the small number of judicial enforcement cases. During the fiscal years 1978-81, EPA initiated 455 cases under section 113(b) but only five required court action. The rest were settled before trial or were dropped at the administrative stage. The CAA only allows fees for court costs; adminis- trative costs are not eligible. If unreasonable enforcement is a problem under the Clean Air Act, then it makes sense to investigate the ex- tension of the indemnification program to other enforce- ment provisions at EPA. However, the recent Equal Ac- cess to Justice Act (EAJA) provides coverage to many of the people who might suffer from unreasonable enforce- ment, and is available for administrative as well as judi- cial hearing costs. Under the EAJA the government must provide attorney fees and court costs for small businesses and individuals in any formal administrative or judical hearing in which the private party prevails and the gov- ernment's position was not substantially justified. Until experience shows that there are unreasonable enforce- ment actions that are not remedied by the EAJA, there is no reason to extend the CAA provisions to other EPA sta- tutes. Indemnification under FIFRA Section 15 of FIFRA provides that when the registration of a pesticide is suspended and then canceled without an opportunity for the owners of the pesticide to sell or use it and if other statutory criteria are met, the owners will receive an indemnity for the cost of the pesticide they own. There have only been three cases which met the conditions since the provision was enacted in 1972. Two of them resulted in minor payments which EPA was able to make out of its own funds. The first totaled approx- imately $53,000 for three people after vinyl chloride was banned for use as an aerosol propellant in pesticide cans. The most recent were two small payments to farmers after the cancellation of most uses of D6CP. The suspen- sion and cancellation of DBCP was done in stages over several years, allowing use of most existing inventories. The largest payments have come as a consequence of the suspension of many registrations of products con- 23 ------- taining Silvex. The suspension was made immediately effective just before the spring growing season of 1979. The suspension was based on new human epidemiology information indicating a correlation between spontaneous abortions and 2,4,5-T spraying, in addition to extensive animal test data which demonstrated that exposure to 2,4,5-T, Silvex, or TCDD results in oncogenicity, tera- togenicity, ferotoxicity, and other adverse reproductive effects. A substantial number of the registrants opposed the cancellation and requested a hearing. However, some of those holding registrations on products for home and gar- den uses containing Silvex did not and cancellation for their products became effective automatically. Nineteen companies, led by Chevron, signed agreements with EPA stipulating that it would not be feasible to reuse the Sil- vex for a non-suspended use, confirming EPA's statutory obligation to dispose of the banned pesticide, and de- scribing the process for processing claims and de- termining cost of the pesticide. EPA relied heavily on the registrants in processing claims. Chevron alone had over 11,000 distributors and retailers of lawn and garden Silvex who were entitled to make claims. Chevron in fact reimbursed its distributors who had given cash or credit to retailers, and Chevron submitted a claim for the total to the government. The claimants also collected the huge amount of Silvex prod- ucts for disposal. EPA sent each claimant a letter stating the amount it considered appropriate, but explaining that the Agency had no funds to pay. The registrants sub- sequently filed in the Court of Claims, where the seven largest claims have been settled for $18.7 million, roughly equal to the amount that EPA found appropriate. They were paid out of the Court of Claims Judgment Fund. The Toxic Substances Control Act For the sake of analysis, we considered a hypothetical ex- tension of the FIFRA indemnification program to TSCA be- cause TSCA is the only other EPA statute under which products may be banned. However, there are several reasons why the FIFRA program may not be a good model. It is the only indemnification program paying directly regulated parties for the cost of valid regulation, none of the statutes covering food, drugs or other consumer prod- ucts do so. Congress has not added such a provision to any legislation since the FIFRA program was enacted, in- dicating that in spite of the difficulty in distinguishing the pesticide situation from others, that Congress intended to treat it as a special case. In any event, we found no evi- dence that TSCA will cause losses beyond the cost of 24 ------- compliance normally allocated to the regulated party, or for any other reason requires an indemnification program. The statute and the subject matter of TSCA allow the Administrator considerable flexibility. The stark choice presented in FIFRA between allowing inventories of dangerous pesticides to be used, or having the gov- ernment pay for them is not presented by TSCA. There are more alternatives, even for emergencies, and more gradations of regulatory action than FIFRA allows. Under TSCA the Administrator must balance the risk of the chemical against the cost of regulation, resulting in the least burdensome requirement consistent with safeguarding public health. The nature of the chemicals under the purview of TSCA also allows regulatory flexibility. Industrial chemicals are often used in a vast number of ways, giving the Agency many ways to reduce risk, for example, by mandating a closed system of production, requiring a label, or banning use in consumer products. If only some uses or processes are banned, there will continue to be a market for the chemical thus reducing the impact on the manufacturer. TSCA also gives the Administrator authority to request a judge to issue a repurchase order. This would com- pensate the downstream processors and users of a chem- ical for their inventory, accomplishing many of the aims of an indemnification program. These are often people who could not be expected to anticipate the Agency's ac- tion, and who had less responsibility for the chemical. Re- purchase orders might also encourage compliance with a ban and disposal order, another argument for the FIFRA indemnification program. There is also a danger that indemnification under TSCA could counter the efforts to encourage voluntary reduc- tion of risk, rather than mandatory regulation. These efforts on the part of EPA and the chemical industry have been increasingly successful. Establishment of an in- demnification program might encourage a company to wait for EPA action, rather than take voluntary actions that could not be compensated in any way. TSCA affirms the continuing responsibility of chemical manufacturers and processors for the safety of their prod- ucts. Thus, indemnification could not be justified by general equity arguments based on the Agency's respon- sibility for registering or evaluating hazardous chemicals. Any individual inequities or errors that might occur under TSCA are difficult to foresee, and impossible to plan for under one indemnification program. Existing indemnifica- tion mechanisms, such as private bills, are available for individual incidents until there is evidence of a need for a comprehensive program. 25 ------- Need For New Indemnification Programs The final step in the study was to search all of the laws and regulations administered by EPA to find any poten- tially indemnifiable losses. Six categories of actions that seemed more likely to result in an indemnifiable loss focused the search: disclosure of confidential business information; delays in issuing permits; conflicting and overlapping requirements; emergency actions; unreasonable administrative enforcement; and changes in agency policy. The search for potentially indemnifiable losses was not limited to these categories, and the categories themselves were refined as additional incidents were discovered. Some were chosen for their similarity to existing pro- grams (unreasonable administrative enforcement), some because they were clearly sources of concern to industry (disclosure of confidential business information), and some because they represent a convergence of several important factors (emergency action presents an in- creased risk of error due to the speed with which de- cisions are made, and may also suspend procedural due process). Industry sources were consulted for identification of potentially indemnifiable losses. (Background Report Appendix C) This included a review of surveys and re- ports on regulatory problems in general, including many that had not specifically addressed indemnification as a solution. Some major trade associations were contacted. Association representatives often referred us to particular members who also provided comments and information. Although the contacts did not amount to a scientific sur- vey, they did offer a fairly broad perspective on industry attitudes toward EPA regulation and the need for in- demnification. 27 ------- Confidential Business Information The possibility that EPA will disclose confidential business information causes concern to those who must report in- formation to EPA. (Background Report p. 122) The greatest cause of concern appears to be authorized dis- closures, either under the Freedom of Information Act (FOIA) or some other statute. Although there have been many attempts to amend FOIA and FIFRA to restrict cur- rently authorized disclosures, there seems to be virtually no industry interest in monetary compensation for such disclosure. Firms appear to believe that prevention is more important than compensation for loss of a business secret. Nor is indemnification warranted for disclosures authorized by Congress. If industry concerns become more pressing a more appropriate solution would be to attempt to change the policy by amending the relevant statutes. A lesser cause of concern is unauthorized disclosure, which may be either negligent or intentional. Erroneously including the formula of a successful Monsanto herbicide in a response to a FOIA request from a presumed com- petitor was a negligent disclosure. Such a loss is difficult to value in monetary terms. Indeed, Monsanto did not sue for money damages. It asked for and received EPA's promise to screen applications for new registrations to catch any that might have been based on the confidential material. There are alternative ways to reduce the risk of loss from unauthorized disclosure. One is prevention of in- advertant disclosure by established procedures to safe- guard confidentiality. There are such procedures in the FOIA regulations; and security manuals, locked file cabinets, and layers of review under TSCA. Deterrence is another approach. Employees can be administratively dis- ciplined for violating the security procedures, and there are criminal sanctions for wrongful disclosure. There are some administrative problems with in- demnification for release of confidential information, under the FTCA or by some other means. It is extremely difficult to calculate the value of information, and es- pecially the loss of confidentiality. Clearly some releases, such as allowing the production volume of a particular chemical to get into the public reading file for a week be- fore it is excised, are less serious than others like the re- lease of the formula of a successful chemical to a com- petitor. Furthermore, some companies would not want to make a claim even if they are aware that information has been released because the claim would draw attention to 28 ------- the information, perhaps disseminating it further. This could endanger its status as a trade secret and thus any chance for collecting damages in a law suit. Should it be decided that there was an undue amount of disclosure and that providing tort liability would in- crease the care with which confidential information is treated, or provide necessary compensation, one solution would be to clarify the FTCA to allow such suits. Evaluating an amendment to the FTCA is beyond the scope of this report, as it would have important im- plications for the rest of the government. However, this study found no evidence of a compelling need for or interest in such a change at this time. Delays in Permit Processing Indemnification does not appear to be a good solution to whatever problems are due to delay in granting permit applications. (Background Report p. 126) Studies have shown that delays usually can not be primarily attributed to regulatory problems. The average processing time for Prevention of Significant Deterioration (PSD) permits at the writing of the Background Report was less than six months from the submission of a complete application to the decision. Both EPA and industry parties concerned with the prob- lem have focused on ways to speed up the process rather than compensating afterwards, and there is no evidence of industry interest in indemnification. Furthermore, the administrative problems of such a program would be con- siderable. It would be very difficult to prove that a delay in a construction project was caused by EPA's delay in issuing the permit, rather than some other factor. Even if it were clear that EPA was taking longer than usual to re- view a permit, it would be difficult to decide whether it was due to the defects in the permit application, the com- plexity of the issues presented, or to negligence. Also, in- demnification would establish counter-productive in- centives for the Agency. The allowable time might be in- adequate for controversial or difficult decisions and thus might foster poor decisions in the most complex cases. EPA might spend too much time documenting its de- cisions, or become reluctant to involve the states for fear that their delay would result in EPA paying indemnifica- tion. In the absence of evidence of a problem, and evidence that indemnification would be an effective response, there is no reason to recommend indemnification for potential losses associated with delay. 29 ------- Regulatory Conflicts and Overlaps A recent GAO report on conflicting and overlapping reg- ulatory requirements found many fewer than might be ex- pected. (Background Report p. 130) There were only four examples involving EPA. One was a consequence of water and air pollution control devices generating sludge. The hazardous wastes in the sludge are then subject to RCRA regulations. Unlike other overlaps, this does not prevent the affected facilities from doing business, although it does increase the cost of compliance with all EPA regulations. The cost of complying with regulations is almost never a basis for indemnification. (Some allege that the tris situation fits the model of conflicting policies because the government first required children's sleep- wear to meet flammability standards and then banned tris. However, there were many ways to meet the stan- dards and not all of the sleepwear was treated with tris even before the ban. Within months of the ban more alternatives were developed, including inherently flame retardant fibers as well as other chemicals.) At least one of the reasons that there are so few ex- amples of conflicting policies is that most of the statutes administered by EPA contain provisions for coordinated policy development. Many also anticipate conflicts by assigning primary responsibility to one office or program to prevent a deadlock. Such provisions appear to represent an expressed preference by Congress on han- dling the potential for conflict. Another reason for lack of conflict in practice is formal agency and interagency re- view of all actions and policies. One of the primary reasons for review is to coordinate action and ensure con- sistency. There is no evidence of conflicts that cannot be resolved through coordination and concurrence, and thus might justify indemnification. Use of Emergency Powers Errors or inequities resulting from the use of emergency powers seemed likely candidates for indemnification, but we found only one incident twelve years ago. (Back- ground Report p. 134) It is worth describing because it was one of the few concrete examples of loss of any kind identified by the study. In 1971, an air pollution emergency developed in Birm- ingham, Alabama before state or federal air pollution con- 30 ------- trol laws were implemented or state officals had authority to address the emergency. After efforts to obtain a volun- tary reduction of paniculate emissions had failed, EPA officials decided to use the emergency authority of sec. 303 of the Clean Air Act for the first time. A temporary restraining order against 23 industrial sources was obtained in the middle of the night without notice to the sources. They were ordered to reduce operations to the extent possible without damage to equipment. By the time of the hearing for the preliminary injunction, the weather had changed, the emergency was passed, and the government attorneys withdrew their petition for the injunction. Some of the attorneys for the sources chal- lenged the ex parte hearing, and the inclusion of their clients in the order. They argued that their clients had in- stalled pollution control equipment, or were too far away to be contributing to the emergency. The order was only in effect for 32 hours and did not result in any damage to equipment, so the losses were limited, but it illustrates the problem with emergency ac- tion. If it is true that some of the facilities were erroneous- ly included in the order, there might be an argument for indemnification because there are no other remedies. The parties had no opportunity to participate in the decision, or to argue for exemptions, and there was no advance notice to allow them to prepare. The impact of the tempo- rary restraining order was irreversible, since it could not be appealed. Another air alert occurred the following spring, after regulations and phased curtailment plans had been writ- ten with the cooperation of the industry. Inspections showed that the industry was complying, and the particu- late counts decreased markedly when the abatement plans went into effect. The abrupt and drastic impact of the first alert was not repeated because the industry had helped plan its response. Emergencies are more likely to raise problems than ac- tions taken on a normal schedule. There are always fewer alternatives available because there is no time for exemp- tion applications to be made and granted, for example. Procedural inequities may occur for the same reason. The incentive effect of indemnification may be helpful in obtaining quick compliance with an emergency order. There are several reasons why an indemnification pro- gram for emergency action is not necessary. It appears that there will be fewer emergency actions than there have been in the past. The development of com- prehensive regulatory programs concerning air and water pollution and spills and leaks of hazardous chemicals has made it less likely that EPA would have to use emergency powers. In addition, by participating in the drafting of 31 ------- regulations and issuing of permits, regulated parties will have had an opportunity to modify the terms of the regu- lation. They are less likely to be harmed unreasonably or surprised by the required response to the emergency. Fur- thermore, the Comprehensive Environmental Response, Compensation and Liability Act (CERCLA or Superfund) provides authority for the government itself to take direct action to clean up or contain a spill without having to order a private party to do it. Responsibility and liability can be determined after reflection. Of course, some emergencies will continue to occur. Emergencies are, almost by definition, unpredictable occurrences. They are difficult to foresee and plan for as each is likely to be different. There are advantages to addressing each separately, rather than attempting to write a broad rule that covers all, but is too general to assist in making a decision on an individual situation. Unreasonable Administrative Enforcement The indemnification program under sec. 113 of the Clean Air Act extends only to costs incurred in a trial, not to those generated by administrative action prior to settle- ment or trial. Thus, administrative enforcement seemed a natural category to examine. (Background Report p. 139) Constraints on enforcement action partially explains the fact that we found very few complaints of unreasonable administrative enforcement by EPA in discussions with current and past officials, trade associations, and in reviewing reports and congressional documents. For ex- ample, the states are the primary enforcers of environ- mental laws. Also, enforcement policy focuses on the most significant violators, reducing the chances that the action will not have a legal justification. Enforcement ac- tions require several levels of concurrence and approval, further reducing the possibilities of harassment or mis- take. The Equal Access to Justice Act (EAJA) provides costs and attorney's fees for individuals and small businesses who prevail against the government, if the government's position is not substantially justified. (Background Report p. 70) This covers many of those presumably most vulner- able to an unreasonable enforcement action because they are less capable of defending themselves. The EAJA should provide relief in most of the incidents in this cate- gory. Certainly there is no need to recommend additional indemnification until shortcomings are discovered in the 32 ------- new law. However, if the EAJA proves insufficient another approach would be to ensure availability of judicial review of the enforcement order before the company must com- ply, where this review is not already available. A new in- demnification program should not be proposed unless a pattern of abuse becomes visible, and these steps are in- adequate. Changes in Agency Policy Consistency and predictability of government action are important to regulated parties. Unexpected changes in policy can disrupt planning and cause losses beyond those attributable to the new policy itself. Further, since industries are not homogenous, a change can affect the relative competitive positions in ways that may not be in- tended, or even foreseen by the Agency. A hypothetical relaxation of effluent standards might be generally re- garded as a benefit to industry, but firms that had in- vested in equipment or process changes to meet the old standards would be at a competitive disadvantage com- pared to those who had never come into compliance. However, the study did not find any actual cases of changes causing a loss that might justify indemnification. Alternatives are helpful in reducing the cost of changes in policy. Advance notice and phased-in compliance can allow those involved to make an orderly transition. Partici- pation of a representative sample of firms during the decision-making can help avoid unwitting impacts on some segments of the industry- Exemptions and waivers permit flexibility in application of new regulations. Most of the statutes administered by EPA allow variances or ex- emptions for various reasons. Another powerful alternative to indemnification for poli- cy changes is review of the decision by administrative or judicial tribunals. The remedies sought are typically not money damages, but modification or retraction of the policy action. This partly explains why we found so few actual losses. If a projected loss is severe or unreasonably allocated, it can often be prevented by obtaining a stay of the action during review. An abrupt change might constitute a procedural inequ- ity, if made in the absence of compelling public health reasons, but the government rarely acts abruptly. Even the emergency decision to suspend the registration for some uses of Silvex and 2,4,5-T just before spring planting came after eight years of regulatory action and research, including one previous cancellation of home and aquatic uses of 2,4,5-T. The manufacturers of the pes- 33 ------- ticides were surely aware of continuing Agency concern and the potential for regulation. However, the sellers and users may not have been as well informed. This points to a possible substantive inequity: that the cost of the action would fall on those least responsible for the public health risk, and least able to bear it. Such an evaluation cannot be made generically or theoretically, but must be based on the facts of a particular situation. Policy decisions are the core of government activity that has always been immune from suit to protect the objectivity of the decision-makers. Changes in policy re- quire the same protection so that the Agency can respond to new information. 34 ------- Costs and Financing of Indemnification Estimating the Cost This report does not recommend any new indemnification programs, and therefore does not contain a cost estimate or discussion of alternative means of financing a particu- lar program as Section 25(a)(1) and (2) of TSCA requested for any programs that might be recommended. However, a general discussion of cost and financing adds an impor- tant dimension to the report. The cost of an average or hypothetical indemnification program is difficult to estimate because the programs vary so widely and so much depends upon the discretion of Congress in a particular case. No formula or universal measure is available in part because so many of the in- demnification payments are made in exceptional situa- tions, those that are unusual and difficult to foresee. Errors by the Agency and product bans fall into this cate- gory. No statistical analysis of the frequency of such los- ses can be made. In other cases the problem is estimating the magnitude of the loss, rather than its frequency. For example, valuing losses that are not financial, such as loss of confidentiality or time lost due to EPA delay in granting a permit, is more difficult than measuring those that are concrete, like lost inventory. Another unknown element is the proportion of the entire loss that Congress would indemnify. Most of the programs do not attempt to reimburse for one hundred percent of the loss. Under the Tris bill, for example, no claim may be made for interest, attorney's fees, or lost profits. Examination of the costs of existing programs is not useful in defining an average because they vary so wide- ly. The arts and artifacts program has required no gov- ernment outlays (except administrative costs), while the swine flu and pesticide programs have cost millions of dollars. Even within a program the costs can vary in ways that are hard to predict. The dairy products indemnity program declined from a peak of $350,000 in annual pay- ments to about $30,000. Last year a very costly incident 35 ------- ocurred in Hawaii that may require up to $7,000,000 in payments. The inability to predict the cost of a program might have a profound effect on support for it and certainly would affect planning and implementation. Congress is naturally reluctant to establish a program without a defi- nite idea of what it will cost. It is also difficult to make the necessary decisions on how the program will be admin- istered and by whom unless the types and frequencies of the losses are known. There are, however, ways to in- troduce more certainty. One is to wait until after the loss has occured to make the indemnification decision. Obviously it is easier to compute the size of a loss that has occurred, than to predict one. Indemnification pay- ments authorized by Congress in response to specific situations have this advantage. In fact, nearly all of the in- demnification programs (with the exception of FIFRA sec. 15) were enacted after some loss had occured. This fur- nished a concrete basis for designing the programs. There are other ways to reduce the uncertainty about future costs. One method is to set a limit for individual payments. A limit may also be placed on total annual ex- penditures. The Arts and Artifacts Indemnity Act, which allows the federal government to promise to indemnify museums for losses they might suffer while exhibiting foreign-owned art or artifacts, limits coverage for an ex- hibit to $50 million, and the total at any one time to $400 million. (Background Report p. A-25) Another method is to provide for review and corrections after a period, as in the Equal Access to Justice Act. (Background Report p. 70). Impact of Indemnification There is very little empirical data from which to judge the impact of indemnification on the actual and potential re- cipients, and upon the government. Thus, it is hard to evaluate the conflicting theories on the subject. Impact on the government The financial impact of indemnification on the gov- ernment depends to some extent upon the method of financing used, and on the size of the indemnification pro- gram. There is no evidence that the current indemnifica- tion programs funded by general revenues are large enough to have an impact on the national economy or on the national budget, even in the aggregate. Where the money comes out of a specific agency's budget, it might have an impact For example, there is reason to believe that builders of waste water treatment plants use the 36 ------- minimum amount of innovation necessary to get the extra 10 percent grant, but not so much innovation that there is really a risk of failure. The money for indemnification would come out of the same fund that is used for the original grants. Thus, every indemnification claim paid will reduce the amount left to subsidize construction. (Background Report p. 57) The theoretical impact of indemnification programs on the government gives rise to arguments both for and against it. One argument made in favor of indemnification is that it would restrain regulatory agencies from over- regulation. Some of the programs we examined appeared to have restraint as a partial goal. FIFRA is one example, as seen in the explicit choice posed between the special rule allowing use of a pesticide whose registration has been cancelled and indemnifying the owners of the pesti- cide. The Clean Air Act (sec. 113) payments for unreason- able enforcement actions were also intended, in part, as a disincentive. Opponents of indemnification fear that the disincentive effect might be more powerful than intended, disuading the government from taking proper regulatory actions, for fear that indemnification claims would be made against it. Clearly, this could be disruptive to the agency's execution of its mandate. There are other ways that Congress could influence the regulatory decisions of the agencies: by es- tablishing clearer statutory standards, by mandating cost effectiveness analysis, or by other means that are more precise and less disruptive than indemnification. Impact on the regulated parties Some have suggested that the promise of indemnifica- tion for losses caused by a new regulatory program would persuade the regulated parties not to oppose its enactment and implementation, thus allowing faster gov- ernment action. It is not at all clear that indemnification could buy-off the opposition. Indemnification is almost never justified for the cost of compliance with a valid regulation, which is the main concern of industry. Further- more, even where indemnification has been granted in the past, it has often not covered the full amount of the losses. Thus, firms would still have reasons to lobby against the statute and to try to influence the regulations, in an attempt to reduce their costs of compliance and minimize other kinds of losses. Furthermore, public par- ticipation is important to a rational regulatory process. It is useful to encourage the comments and assistance of those who have expertise on the subject, so that the reg- ulations are as accurate and effective as possible. There is also a commonly expressed concern that the availability of indemnification could reduce self-scrutiny 37 ------- by the private sector. For example, if a company knows that it will be indemnified for the cost of a hazardous product when it is banned, it might be inclined to wait for EPA to ban the product rather than to do tests, detect the hazards, and voluntarily withdraw the product from the market. There is no evidence in this study that the availability of indemnification has had such an effect. In many cases, the promise of indemnification was uncertain or conditional, and in every case evidence of negligence by the party claiming indemnification was sufficient to bar a claim for indemnification. Impact On The Background Report analyzed the impact of in- investment damnification in a hypothetical FIFRA ban and a hypothe- tical ban of a chemical under TSCA. One of the primary arguments made for FIFRA indemnification was that it was necessary to maintain investment in research and in- novation. In the FIFRA scenario the cash flow of a pesti- cide was analyzed by the net present value method to de- termine the impact of indemnification on the initial in- vestment decision. (Background Report E-11) The cash flow of pesticides is negative for many years as the manufacturer invests in research, development, produc- tion and promotion. Thus, if a pesticide is cancelled soon after registration, the manufacturer may suffer a heavier loss than if it is later in the pesticide's life cycle. Also, the inventories of pesticides fluctuate enormously over the year, because use is seasonal. A cancellation just before the growing season would result in a higher inventory loss than one during the season. The possibility that EPA might cancel a pesticide increases the risk to the manu- facturer. The promise of indemnification for inventory costs reduces that risk to some extent. The cash flow analysis shows that indemnification would raise the after-tax net present value by different amounts depending upon the assumptions chosen. How- ever, even when a high expected cancellation rate is assumed, the expected net present value of the pesticide is increased by less than one percent; probably not enough to influence decision making for most companies. The real loss is in the future profits that must be fore- gone. This conclusion agrees with anecdotal evidence gathered from industry representatives. A similar, though less detailed, analysis was done for a hypothetical "average" chemical in TSCA's jurisdiction. (Background Report p.E-5) The conclusion agrees with that for pesticides, that indemnification would not signifi- cantly alter the initial investment decision. This again is due to the fact that indemnification of inventory losses would only cover a fraction of the total loss. 38 ------- The impact of indemnification on distributors and users is even less. The primary users of chemicals are the man- ufacturers themselves. They might hold smaller in- ventories or be less likely to use those chemicals with high probability of being banned. However, the dominant factor is still likely to be the technical efficacy of the chemical. Financing Like any other government program, indemnification could be funded in a variety of ways. There are many var- iations on basic options for financing a program and dis- tributing the benefits. The four basic options for dis- tributing government benefits are: • cash payments; • assumption of liability by the government; • tax assistance; and • credit assistance. The four basic options for funding are: • appropriations from general tax revenues (either by regular or special appropriations); • appropriations from dedicated revenue sources; • revolving fund account (initially funded by general or dedicated taxes, but perpetuated by repayments of loans or recoveries of expended funds); and • tax expenditures. Several commentators have suggested that it would be economically efficient if the beneficiaries of government action compensated those who suffer losses because of it. Although this principle might work for economic regula- tions, such as the deregulation of an industry, it is not generally applicable to health and safety regulation. In economic regulation, a concrete and often monetary benefit is transferred from one identifiable group to an- other; for example from the owners of truck certificates for certain routes to all the additional trucking companies that are able to compete for business on the routes after de-regulation. It is more difficult to value the benefits from banning a hazardous chemical and to identify the beneficiaries. There is also a question about the equity of requiring victims to pay for the alleviation of a problem they did not create. There are neither economic efficiency 39 ------- nor equity reasons to require those living next to an aban- doned waste site to bear the cost of a government con- tractor's negligence, or the cost of insuring against it. The winners and losers scheme is even more difficult to apply to non-regulatory actions including errors by the gov- ernment and incentives to private actions. Existing indemnity programs illustrate many of the pos- sible combinations of funding and distribution options and reasons for choosing them. Cash payments from regular appropriations. An example of this alternative is the USDA's payment of compensa- tion for milk and milk products contaminated by pesti- cides that were registered at the time of their use. USDA includes a budget for this program in its request each year. The payments are actually made by checks drawn on USDA's general fund account. This alternative can be relatively efficient in handling frequent and predictable claims. The recent discovery of heptachlor in all of the milk in Hawaii caused losses far beyond the amount budgeted. However, it was a relatively simple matter, with the program already in place, to appropriate the addition- al funds needed. Cash payments from special appropriations after the event. This alternative works for less frequent events for which annual appropriations are not necessary. By seeking funding after the loss occurs, the recipient has less certainty of being paid and probably cannot be moti- vated by the more remote possibility of repayment. How- ever, it can still reduce an inequity. The government may find it easier to decide to pay the indemnity because all the facts are known, and the amount of money needed is definite. An extreme example is the Arts and Artifacts In- demnification Program, administered by the National En- dowment for the Arts. The NEA is authorized to pledge the full faith and credit of the United States to indemnify museums for loss or damage to works of art while in ex- hibit in the United States or overseas. No money is appropriated until the museum suffers a loss which is in- vestigated and certified to the Congress. A special appro- priation will then be made. For programs in which claims occur on an infrequent basis (no claims have yet been made to Congress under the arts program) and where the amounts of the claims are upredictable, after-the-fact appropriations will be more appropriate. Backed by statutory authority to ensure even- tual payment this approach provides credibility while avoiding unnecessary budgeting for funds. 40 ------- Cash payments from dedicated tax revenues. This alternative differs from the previous two in that revenues come from special taxes or fees assessed on a designated class of individuals (i.e., the users of a certain product) or companies, or a designated product (certain chemical feedstocks). The revenues can be generated continuously to meet routine and predicted requirements, or per- iodically to meet non-routine needs or to replenish funds from previous payouts. The relationship between the bene- ficiaries and those from whom the taxes are collected can create a variety of incentives and disincentives. Con- gress could maintain oversight and control through con- tribution of a portion of the funds. Cash payments from a revolving fund. A revolving fund is a pool of money out of which indemnity payments can be made. It is regularly replenished through repayment or recovery of expended funds. It is not unusual for such funds to be initially funded and supplemented from general or special appropriations. The key aspect is that they are in some form self-sustaining. This characteristic reduces the need for appropriations and provides in- centives for good fiscal management by the agency re- sponsible. However, a self-sustaining fund is somewhat independent of Congress, circumventing one of the more effective means of Congressional oversight. Section 311 of the Clean Water Act (oil spill compensa- tion) and Superfund both have revolving fund characteris- tics. Funds expended for cleanup activities are later re- covered if a responsible party can be found and if the party is solvent. Direct assumption of liability by the government. An assumption of the underlying risk by the government can provide a substantial economic benefit though no pay- ment is made. The government might or might not es- tablish a means of paying for the loss before it occurs. The swine flu program is an example. Vaccine manu- facturers were so concerned about potential suits that they demanded protection before they would manufacture the vaccine. The Congress finally agreed to make the sole cause of action one against the government. (The gov- ernment may, in turn, sue manufacturers for negligently caused harms, but manufacturers are thus protected from suits based on strict liability that some state tort systems allow.) The cost of administering this form of indemnifica- tion is very high. Over four thousand claims have been filed with the Department of Justice, and each must be assessed, denied, settled or litigated. 41 ------- Special tax credit resulting in reduced tax revenues. A number of alternatives involve foregoing tax revenues for various purposes. Foregoing revenue has the same net effect on the government as paying out an indemnity claim. Losses suffered by reason of agency actions are usually eligible for deductions as ordinary business expenses. Thus some tax assistance is always available. At times, Congress has been explicit in declaring these losses eligi- ble for deduction, though not for indemnification. The tax bill of 1981 contained such a provision. (26 U.S.C. 165 note) Truck certificates which formerly had considerable value were rendered worthless when the trucking industry was deregulated. Congress used the tax bill to make clear its view that the trucking firms could deduct the book value of the certificates. Tax credits provide a greater benefit. Eligible firms can actually reduce tax liability by a specified amount. Firms with taxes less than the amount of the allowable credit, could be allowed to defer the credit to another year or sell it to another firm. Tax credit devices are relatively simple to operate, reducing the complexity of transferring an economic benefit to the indenmified parties. However, they should only be applied to very large programs affecting many people or firms. The required changes in tax forms and reference materials can only be justified by the wide- spread use of the new provision. d2_ ------- Conclusions There are no patterns of loss or potential loss which war- rant a new indemnification program for EPA at this time. This is due in part to the efficacy of the alternatives to in- demnification that prevent loss and shift and spread the losses that do occur. Other potential losses are similar to those occuring under many federal laws and have been addressed by general legislation applying to all gov- ernment actions. Furthermore, programs will be better de- signed if they respond to a loss that has already occurred rather than to the hypothetical possibility of one. Because we found no such losses, and none were brought to our attention by industry, recommendation of a program is premature. However, two related situations merit further study. The risks in experimenting with innovative technology and the risks of government contractors doing hazardous work may be addressed either by private insurance purchased by the government as part of the grant or contract or by indemnification. A quantitative comparison of the relative costs and efficacy would aid decisions on which method to use in a particular situation. The fact that there is no current situation justifying a new indemnification program does not mean that there will not be one in the future. Even more likely are in- dividual instances in which the government ought to make a single indemnification payment. There are es- tablished mechanisms through which Congress can grant extraordinary relief, including indemnification. One is pri- vate legislation, bills of specific rather than general application. Another is a grant of special jurisdiction to the U.S. Claims Court to hear and award claims which would otherwise be precluded by law. Such procedures allow Congress to make special exceptions for political or equitable reasons without adding a permanent federal re- sponsibility or establishing a new legal principle. This appears to be the appropriate response as many of the losses and potential losses are themselves exceptions 43 ------- resulting from unusual circumstances of an individual case rather than the normal workings of an EPA statute or program. An analysis of the claim using the factors identified in this report will help to shape a decision on whether par- ticular incidents should be indemnified and whether an in- dividual response will suffice or a program is needed. Ul- timately, the decision to indemnify for regulatory losses is a political one. By its nature as an idiosyncratic safety valve and exception from general legal principles, in- demnification cannot be reduced to a formula. Such polit- ical decisions must be made by an elected political body. 44 ------- EPA Indemnification Programs Program Sec. 311(i) of the Clean Water Act (Background Report p. 78) Sec. 202 of the Clean Water Act (Background Report p. 53) Sec. 113 of the Clean Air Act (Background Report p. 66) Sec. 15 of the Federal In- secticide, Fungicide and Rodenticide Act (Background Report p. 33) Description Reimbursement to innocent parties for cost of cleaning up oil spills. Funding Claims filed in Court of Claims; pay- ment from sec. 311(k) fund reple- nished by appropriations, penalties and recovered costs. Payment for cost of repair or replace- Indemnification is by discretionary ment of failed innovative or alterna- grant paid out of fund for construc- tive technology in wastewater treat- tion of treatment works. ment plants. Attorney fees and court costs may be Awarded by judge in the enforce- awarded to those against whom EPA ment case, paid out of Judgment brings an unreasonable enforcement Fund. action. Payment to owner for the value of in- No funding mechanism in FIFRA. ventories of a pesticide after emergency suspension and cancella- tion of the pesticides's registration. Cases 45 claims between 1973-1981. Aver- age payment for successful claim is $39,000. Few plants have been completed under the program, and very few claims made. Only one $10,000 payment and one claim since 1977. Used three times since 1972 enact- ment; for 3 small vinyl chloride pro- peliant claims, a few small DBCP claims and over 18 million dollars of claims concerning Silvex. ------- Non-EPA Indemnification Examples o> Program Incentives Arts & Artifacts (Background Report p. A-25) Diseased Animals (Background Report p. A-18) Government Contractors Swine Flu Vacine (Backgound Report p. A- 23) NASA Contractors (Background Report p. A-26) Non-Policy Error Equal Access to Justice Act (Background Report p. A-70) Description Full faith and credit of U.S. to insure museums against loss connected with international exhibitions. Limit on coverage per exhibit and total coverage per year. Department of Agriculture pays scheduled amounts for animals de- stroyed because diseased or exposed to certain diseases. Funding Financing by special appropriation after loss is certified. Museums also required to carry some commercial insurance. Financed as budget item, by regular appropriations. Government agreed to assume strict Claims awarded by judge or agreed liability for making and administering to in settlement. Paid out of Judg- swine flu vacine where state law rec- ment Fund. ognized such claims. Suits filed against federal government. Users of space shuttle indemnified above liability insurance. (NASA may also indemnify contractors engaged in activities that are "unusually hazardous" or "facilitate the national defense") Individuals and small businesses get Statute ambiguous, but probably will attorney's fees and court costs if they come out of Agency budgets. prevail and the government position is not substantially justified. Cases No requests for payment from Con- gress yet made, but museums have saved over $11 million in insurance premiums. Thousands of claims over many years. Claims run in cycles as dis- eases spread or are controlled. Over 4,000 claims made for $3 bil- lion. For 667 successful claims, $64.3 million awarded. Over 14,000 administrative pro- ceedings during first year potentially covered, but only 103 applications for fees filed; 49 with NLRB, 15 with Armed Services Board of Contract Appeals. ------- Cranberry Incident (Background Report p. A-20) Mizokami Brothers Spinach (Background Report p. A-20) Marlin Toys (Background Report p. A-21) Pesticides Beekeepers (Background Report p. A-19) Dairy Products (Background Report p. A-19) Ban Tris-treated Children's Sleepwear (Background Report p. A-22) Growers of uncontaminated berries indemnified for loss of sales following HEW announcement about some contaminated cranberries. An administrative decision. FDA test mistakenly showed con- tamination of Mizokami Brothers' spi- nach. Private bill conferred special jurisdiction on Court of Claims to award judgment. Mistaken inclusion of toy on holiday list of banned products. Agency sup- ported private bill referring matter to Court of Claims under Congressional Reference procedure. Because pesticides replacing DDT were more harmful to bees, program indemnified beekeepers for bees kil- led by non-negligent pesticide use. Program lasted from 1969-81. Dairy farmers indemnified for milk and milk products contaminated with pesticides providing dairy farmer was not negligent. When tris-reated children's sleep- wear was banned as a cancer hazard, much of the loss fell on relatively small cutters and sewers. Private bill confered special jurisdiction on the Court of Claims to award judgment. Paid out of existing USDA fund from customs duties to be used to "rees- tablish farmer's purchasing power", among other things. Approximately $300,000 paid out of Judgment Fund. Mostly for spinach Mizokami destroyed while error was contested. Congressional Reference requires special appropriation to carry out recommendation of Court of Claims, in this case to pay Marlin $40,000. Apparently Congress never did appropriate the money. Regular appropriations. A single case. Regular appropriations. Court of Claims Judgment Fund, after award by judge according to criteria set out in special bill. A single case. A single case. Many thousands over life of pro- gram. Payments according to sched- ule, after certification of non- negligence by beekeeper. Many over the years. Annual pay- ment now reduced to 10% of peak of $350,000, but 1982 incident in Hawaii may result in $7 million in claims. Estimated total approximately $50 million. ------- |