EPA-R5-73-016
APRIL 1973             Socioeconomic Environmental Studies Series
Economic  Feasibility of Minimum
Industrial  Waste  Load
Discharge  Requirements
                               Office of Research and Monitoring
                               U.S. Environmental Protection Agency
                               Washington, O.C 20460

-------
            RESEARCH REPORTING SERIES
Research reports of the  Office  of  Research  and
Monitoring,  Environmental Protection Agency, have
been grouped into five series.  These  five  broad
categories  were established to facilitate further
development  and  application   of   environmental
technology.   Elimination  of traditional grouping
was  consciously  planned  to  foster   technology
transfer   and  a  maximum  interface  in  related
fields.  The five series are:

   1.  Environmental Health Effects Research
   2.  Environmental Protection Technology
   3.  Ecological Research
   U.  Environmental Monitoring
   5.  Socioeconomic Environmental Studies

This report has been assigned to the SOCIOECONOMIC
ENVIRONMENTAL   STUDIES   series.    This   series
describes  research on the socioeconomic impact of
environmental problems.  This covers recycling and
other  recovery  operations   with   emphasis   on
monetary incentives.  The non-scientific realms of
legal   systems,  cultural  values,  and  business
systems  are  also  involved.   Because  of  their
interdisciplinary  scope,  system  evaluations and
environmental management reports are  included  in
this series.

-------
                                              EPA-R5-73-016
                                              April 1973
           ECONOMIC FEASIBILITY  OF MINIMUM

 INDUSTRIAL WASTE LOAD DISCHARGE REQUIREMENTS
                        By

                 Henry C. Bramer
             Contract  No. 68-01-0196
               Project No. 2800775
                 Project Officer

                 Donald H. Lewis
       Implementation Research Division
        Environmental Protection Agency
             Washington, D. C.  20460
                  Prepared for

       OFFICE OF RESEARCH AND MONITORING
     U.S. ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY
              WASHINGTON, D. C.   20460
For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office, Washington, D.C. 20402
            Price $2.10 domestic postpaid or $1.70 OPO Bookstore

-------
                EPA Review Notice
This report has been reviewed by the Environmental
Protection Agency and approved for publication.
Approval does not signify that the contents
necessarily reflect the views and policies of the
Environmental Protection Agency, nor does mention
of trade names or commercial products constitute
endorsement or recommendation for use.

-------
                         ABSTRACT
This study presents order-of-magnitude estimates of the
costs of implementing minimum and zero discharge require-
ments for the manufacturing and electric power industries.
The analysis was made, for the most part, at the 2 digit
S.I.C. level for the manufacturing industries.  The assumed
technology was maximum in-plant recirculation and reuse,
concentration of the recirculation blowdown by evaporation,
and final residual disposal by the applicable least-cost
method among incineration, deepwell disposal, solar
evaporation, and ocean disposal.

It is concluded that a strict zero discharge requirement
would have greatly variable and significant economic con-
sequences, but that less stringent definitions of minimum
discharge would be feasible.  The limiting factors in
applying a strict zero discharge requirement appear to be
the availability of physical resources, particularly energy,
for purposes of effluent concentration.
                         111

-------
                         CONTENTS




Section                                                Paqe
  I     Conclusions                                     1



  II    Recommendations                                 3



  III   Introduction                                    5



  IV    Industrial Water Utilization                    7



  V     Alternative Definitions of Minimum Discharge   17



  VI    Definitions of Costs                           23



  VII   Available Technology for Minimum Discharge     35



  VIII  Residual Effluent Disposal                     39



  IX    Costs of Industry Systems for Zero Discharge   51



  X     Economic Analysis                              77



  XI    Acknowledgements                               97



  XII   References                                     99



  XIII  Appendices                                    101
                         v

-------
                           FIGURES
                                                        PAGE
 1  SCHEMATIC OF  INDUSTRIAL WATER UTILIZATION
    (ALL  INDUSTRIES  -  TOTAL)  1968                         9

 2  SCHEMATIC OF  INDUSTRIAL WATER UTILIZATION
    (PETROLEUM AND COAL  PRODUCTS  -S.I.C.  29) 1968        9

 3  SCHEMATIC OF  INDUSTRIALMTER  UTILIZATION
    (CHEMICAL AND ALLIED PRODUCTS -S.I.C.  28)  1968     10

 4  SCHEMATIC OF  INDUSTRIAL WATER UTILIZATION
    (PAPER AND ALLIED  PRODUCTS  -  S.I.C.  26)  1968        10

 5  SCHEMATIC OF  INDUSTRIAL WATER UTILIZATION
    (LUMBER AND WOOD PRODUCTS - S.I.C.  24)  1968         11

 6  SCHEMATIC OF  INDUSTRIAL WATER UTILIZATION
    (TEXTILE MILL PRODUCTS - S.I.C.  22)  1968              11

 7  SCHEMATIC OF  INDUSTRIAL WATER UTILIZATION
    (FOOD AND KINDRED  PRODUCTS  -S.I.C.  20)  1968        12

 8  SCHEMATIC OF  INDUSTRIALV&TER  UTILIZATION
    (PRIMARY METAL INDUSTRIES -  S.I.C.  33)  1968           12

 9  DEFINITION NO- 1 - ZERO LIQUID  DISCHARGE WITH
    UNDERGROUND STORAGE  OF  SOLIDS                       19

10  DEFINITION NO. 2 - DISCHARGE  ONLY  HEAT AND  d.s.
    AT INTAKE CONCENTRATIONS                             19

11  DEFINITION NO. 3 - DISCHARGE  ONLY  HEAT AND  INTAKE
    DISSOLVED SOLIDS                                    20

12  DEFINITION NO. 4 - DISCHARGE  ONLY  HEAT AND
    DISSOLVED SOLIDS                  "                  20

13  AVERAGE ANNUAL PRECIPITATION  FOR THE UNITED STATES  44

14  AREAS OF POTENTIAL INJECTION  SITES (SEDIMENTARY
    BASINS)                                               45

15  TOTAL ANNUALIZED RESIDUAL DISPOSAL COSTS            49

16  MARKET EFFECTS OP AN  ADDED  TAX  WITH ELASTIC DEMAND  92

17  MARKET EFFECTS OF AN  ADDED  TAX  WITH INELASTIC
    DEMAND                                               92
                              VI

-------
Figures  (con't.)



                                                        PAGE




18  DEMAND AND SUPPLY  -  STEEL INDUSTRY (1967-72)         93




19  INCREASED DOMESTIC COST  AND IMPORTS                 94
                              Vll

-------
                          TABLES


No.                                                     Page

1   Water Use Statistics (All Industries - Total) 1968     8

2   Conventional Fossil-Fueled Electric Power Plants       7

3   Nuclear Electric Power Plants                         13

4   Projected Electric Power Plant Capacity and
      Generation                                          13

5   Projected Electric Power Plant Waste Loads            15

6   Definitions of Minimum Discharge                      18

7   Initial Cost Estimates                                21

8   Asset Guideline Periods as Established by the
      Internal Revenue Service                            25

9   Estimated Depreciation Rates for Buildings and
      Equipment                                           26

10  Capital Cost Components                               31

11  Components of Operating Costs                         32

12  Total Costs of Industrial Water Use                   33

13  Water Use Cost Components                             33

14  Water Use Costs Less Depreciation                     34

15  Average Operating Cost Components                     34

16  Steel Industry Water Use Data                         35

17  Total Costs of Ocean Disposal                         39

18  Capital and Operating Costs of Ocean Disposal         40

19  Deepwell Disposal Costs                               41

20  Costs of Solar Evaporation Ponds and Conveyance       41

21  Solar Evaporation Costs                               42

22  Mean Monthly Computed Reservoir Evaporation at
      Selected Stations, in Inches Depth                  43
                            Vlll

-------
Tables (con't.)


                                                        Page

23  Gross Water Uses and Water Intakes of Brackish
      and Fresh Tidewaters by State                       46

24  Summary of Water Uses and Residual Disposal Means     47

25  Summary of Costs of Residual Disposal Means           48

26  Numbers of Large Water-Using Establishments           52

27  Projected Primary Metal Industries Shipments          52

28  Brine Disposal Means - S.I.C. 33                      55

29  Summary of Costs - Primary Metals Industries -
      S.I.C. 33                                           59

30  Existing Practice Waste Loads                         60

31  Stream Standards Waste Loads                          60

32  Minimum Discharge Waste Loads                         60

33  Intake Dissolved Solids Discharged in Brine           60

34  Zero Discharge Residuals                              61

35  Electric Power Industry Waste Water Parameters        62

36  Power Plant Cooling Water Use                         63

37  Power Plant Distillation Costs                        63

38  Power Plant Brine Production                          63

39  Percentage Distribution of Disposal Means -
      Electric Power Industry                             66

40  Electric Power Industry - Cost and Discharge
      Summary                                             67

41  Summary of Costs and Residual Waste Loads, Primary
      Metals                                              68

42  Summary of Costs and Residual Waste Loads, Paper
      and Allied Products                                 69

43  Summary of Costs and Residual Waste Loads,
      Chemicals and Allied Products                       70

-------
Tables (con1 t. )
No.
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
61
62
63
Summary of Costs and Residual Waste Loads,
Petroleum and Coal Products
Summary of Costs and Residu-al Waste Loads,
Food and Kindred Products
Summary of Costs and Residual Waste Loads,
Textile Mills
Summary of Costs and Residual Waste Loads, Totals
of Manufacturing Industries Studied
Summary of Costs and Residual Waste Loads,
Electric Power Industry
Summary of Costs and Residual Waste Loads, Total
Manufacturing Industries
Values of Shipments in Large Water-Using Plants
Costs, Production and Water Use Data - 1968
Pollution Control Cost Comparisons
Industry Costs and Profit Effects - 1968
Allocations of Control Costs
1968 After-Tax Profit Effects
After-Tax Profit Effects - Large Water-Using
Plants
After-Tax Profit Effects - Entire Industries
Profit Reductions due to Zero Discharge
Expenditures for Control vs Total Capital
Expenditures
Pollution Control Costs as Percentages of Capital
Expenditures
Cost Increases due to Wage Increases
Added Control Costs vs Wage Increase Costs
Added Control Costs as Percentage Wage Increases
Pag
71
72
73
74
75
78
77
80
79
81
79
82
83
84
84
85
85
86
87
87

-------
Tables (con't.)

No.                                                    Page

64   Profit Positions of Various Industries             88

65   Price Increases due to Zero Discharge              89

66   Comparative Invested Capital and Profitability
       Selected Industry Leaders - Year 1971           118
                           XI

-------
                         SECTION I

                        CONCLUSIONS

This study has indicated that the costs of implementing
a strict definition of zero discharge of liquid effluents
from industrial and electric power plants would be
approximately 3.3 times as much as the present costs of
attaining ambient water quality standards  (stream stan-
dards) and would have cost an additional $4.9 billion
annually in 1972.  The added capital investment in 1972
would have totaled about $17.6 billion.  The additional
capital investment required would have been about 50
percent of the annual expenditures for new plant and equip-
ment by the manufacturing and electric power industries.
The added cost of implementing zero discharge would have
been equivalent to a 3 percent rise in wage rates and would
probably have reduced after-tax profits by 15 percent in
the short run.  By 1980 the added costs would increase to
approximately $6.8 billion annually in terms of 1972
dollars.

The costs involved vary widely among the various industries.
The burden of the paper industry would be the greatest by
almost any measure employed.  Overall price increases of
the order of 3 percent would probably be involved in pro-
ducts and power at the manufacturing level if costs were
to be recovered by means of price increases.  The steel
industry, in particular, would have difficulty passing along
such added costs in the face of the availability of lower-
cost imports.

A minimum discharge requirement which would minimize
effluent volumes and permit the discharge of the residual
effluent if treated to meet existing water quality standards
would cost only about one-fifth as much as would zero dis-
charge requirements.  Such a requirement would have a sig-
nificant economic impact only on the paper industry.

The limiting factors in implementing zero discharge appear
to be the physical resources required, particularly for
means to effect effluent volume reductions beyond those
attainable by maximum recirculation and reuse of water within
a plant.  The energy requirements of evaporation, as well as
the capacity to produce such equipment, appear to be unreal-
istically high.

Residual disposal site availability does not appear to
offer constraints of a similar magnitude.

-------
It is concluded, at this level of analysis,  that imple-
mentation of a strict definition of zero discharge of
liquid effluents from industrial plants is not feasible
in the near future, i.e., utilizing technology that is
clearly available.

-------
                        SECTION II

                      RECOMMENDATIONS

The present study has defined the order-of-magnitude costs
of minimum and zero discharge within several constraints
which affect the accuracy of the estimates.  The more sig-
nificant of these are analysis of the manufacturing
industries at only the 2-digit S.I.C. level, the assump-
tion of uniform unit costs of recirculation, the assumption
of the sole use of evaporation as a concentration method,
the assumed need of uniform discharge requirements among
all industries, and the assumptions of uniform costs of
capital and depreciation periods.

It is recommended that the following additional studies be
accomplished utilizing computer methods so that the costs
can be developed and segregated at a more disaggregated
level and so that the effects of new data and information
can be quickly evaluated in the future.

1.  Determine the costs of implementing a definition of
minimum discharge that would allow the discharge of heat
and dissolved solids in recirculated cooling water blowdowns
but prohibit process water discharge.

2.  Determine the applicability and availability of alter-
native concentration technologies in various specific
industry groups, including the availability of waste heat
and the heating values of waste materials for evaporation
and incineration, and energy requirements for the optimum
methods.

3.  Determine in detail the likelihood of changes in pro-
duction and waste treatment technology due to minimum dis-
charge requirements, including effects on the total
environment.

4.  Determine the extent to which discharges as in (1) can
be minimized in the various industries without the con-
straint of uniform requirements between industry groups.

5.  Determine the extent to which the costs incurred as
above would affect each industry, including the probable
ability to pass on these costs.

-------
                        SECTION III

                       INTRODUCTION

It has been the purpose of this study to determine the
economic feasibility of requirements that industrial
water effluents be minimized or eliminated.  The analysis
has, for the most part, been at the 2-digit S.I.C. level
in the manufacturing industries and has included the
electric power industry.

Various levels of discharge restrictions have been con-
sidered as being the basis for definition of minimum
discharge.  Zero discharge is considered in the strictest
sense, i.e., no liquid effluent to a surface body of water.
Ultimate disposal of final residuals to the land, air,
underground aquifer, and ocean environments have been
assumed.

The analysis has been predicated on the use of maximum
in-plant recirculation and reuse, concentration of the
recirculation system blowdown by evaporation, and final
residual disposal by deepwell injection, solar evaporation,
incineration, ocean disposal, landfill; the final residual
disposal method being the applicable least-cost means.
Evaporation for concentration has been considered because
it is the only clearly applicable present technology for
which reliable cost data are readily available.  Treatment
for in-plant recirculation and reuse has been assumed equal
to the effluent quality requirements for discharge.

All cost data within the body of the report are in 1968
dollars.  All necessary reductions of costs to the 1968
basis have been made on the basis of an annual cost infla-
tion of 3.5 percent.  The base year was chosen because it
is the year of the most recent Census of Manufactures data
and the base year for the Cost of Clean Water industry
profiles which were used as defining terminal treatment
costs.  Only in the Conclusions have costs been expressed in
current dollars (1972).

Costs are generally expressed in annualized terms.  Operating
costs are used throughout as excluding capital charges.
Annualized capital costs are based upon a 10-year life and
an interest rate of 8 percent.

Where references are made to the large water-using industrial
plants, this means those plants taking in more than 20
million gallons of water annually and is in accordance with
the Census of Manufactures usage.  Values added and value of
shipments in those plants are as defined in Water Use in
Manufacturing, Census of Manufactures and refer only to those
plants within an industry.

-------
                        SECTION IV

               INDUSTRIAL WATER UTILIZATION

Any study of minimum industrial water discharges must
take into account not only the volumes of water involved,
but also the particular uses to which portions of the
water used are put.  The uses largely determine the
maximum degree of re-use and thus the final volumes which
must be considered for treatment and/or ultimate disposal
beyond effluent quality requirements, i.e., requirements
to meet water quality standards.

The data of Table 1 show overall water use practices in
the manufacturing industries in plants taking in more
than 20 million gallons annually according to the 1967
Census of Manufactures.  The numbers in parentheses were
calculated by difference for the most part.  The quanti-
ties of water discharged by use were calculated by the
ratios of total discharge to total use times the water
intake by purpose.  These data are shown graphically in
Figure 1.  The schematics of Figure 2 through 8 show
similar data for each of the 7 major water-using industries,
derived in the same way as for Figure 1.

No such data were available for the electric power industry.
Water use data for the electric power industry were deve-
loped as shown below on the basis of known water uses and
projected numbers of plants, capacities, and efficiencies
through 1980.
 Table 2.  Conventional Fossil-Fueled Electric Power Plants
                         1957
1967
1968
1969
1,039
99,500
497.2
57
971
210,237
974.1
53
979
226,020
1,072.9
54
981
241,355
1,159.8
55
No- of Plants
Installed Capacity, mw
Net Generation, 10  kwh
Plant Factor, %

     Scheduled new plants and additions, 1970-1977

     No. of plants     67
     Capacity, mw 134,300

Federal Power Commission, January, 1971, Steam -
Electric Plant Construction Cost and Annual
Production Expenses.

-------
Table 1.  Water Use Statistics  (All Industries - Total)  19C«
Parameter
Water Intake, Total
Fresh Water Co. Systems
Fresh Water Public Systems
Brackish Water
Treated Prior to Use
Water Discharged, Total
Treated Prior to Discharge
Water Used, Total
Process Uses
Air Conditioning
Steam Electric Power
Cooling and Condensing
Boiler Fead and Sanitary
All
Establishments
15,. 167
10,862
1,592
3,013
3,506
14,276
4,353
35,701
(10,245)
( 1,108)
( 4,361)
(18,312)
( 1,675)
Establishments
Recirculating
Water
13,171.
9,403
1,317
2,451
3,249
12,063
3,960
33,405
9,460
1,069
4,050
17,233
1,534
Onco-through
Water Users
( 2,296)
( 1,459)
( 275)
( 562)
( 257)
( 2,213)
( 393)
( 2,296)
( 785)
( 39)
( 311)
( 1,019)
( 141)
Water Discharged:

   Public Utility Sewers
   Surface Water Body
   Tidewater Body
   Ground Water
   To Other Users

Water Intake by Purpose:

   Process Uses
   Air Conditioning
   Steam Electric Power
   Cooling and Condensing
   Boiler Feed and Sanitary

Water Discharged by Use:

   Process Water
   Air Conditioning
   Steam Electric Power
   Cooling and Condensing
   Boiler Feed and Sanitary
                         1,022
                         9,545
                         3,316
                           190
                           203
                         4,295
                           249
                         3,009
                         6,877
                         1,036
                       C 3,972)
                       (.   230)
                       ( 2,771)
                       ( 6,347)
                       (   956)
   769
 8,163
 2,825
   144
   164
 3,510
   210
 2,698
 5,658
   895
(3,215)
(  192)
(2,471)
(5,365)
(  820)
  253)
1,382)
  491)
   46)
   39)
  785)
   39)
  311)
1,019)
  141)
  757)
   38)
  300)
  982)
  136)

-------
| FRESH WATER CO. SYSTEMS | | praSc^YSTEMS
BRACKISH WATER |
s s "
LOSSES S H °
M
00
Once-thtough
users
7571 -1 785
• 1 PROCESsU*. 	
38l MR | , 39
ICOND. _J*^
^ ^nni STEAM 1 f-m
~* ISANIT'Y]
[LOS
393
1820
FIGURE 1.
LOSSES
H
Once- through.
users
0 { STEAM I _ fl
I ELECT.!
-^Hpaafr"^
~* IsAHIT' j *
[LOS
19
103
er»
n
o
cs
« 257
0
i-H
in
m'

CTi
ro
WASTE
*""" TREA
m
IT)
fO
•*
9460
M
CTi
H
CTi
10
f^
1069 1 '
H
r*
•v
(N
4050
tn
\D
ro
m
17293 - ^^34 1
cs
GO
n in •* «r
U> CN] VO <<4>
H O3 H H
00, (S], ,
WATER P UBLI C S URF ACE
njg^. UTILITY WATER BODY
SEWERS
m
in
tN
TIDEWATER
BODY
TO OTHER GROUND
USERS WATER
(N r-( Of 10
00' CT1 ' (*)' ^
n T*
i-H
SCHET1ATIC OF INDUSTRIAL WATER UTILIZATION CALL INDUSTRIES, TOTAL) - 1968
IPRESH WATER co. SYSTEMS | | p,™*™™,
BRACKISH WATER
9> H in
ro CO rH
U> H U>
o
o\
o
o
rsi
in
•^"
H
H

a 33 TNTaifR WATKB TPWaTMWMT 167 ^
CO
00

Recirculating Users
ro
PROCESS A
WATER "^ CONDIT
m
r-
QPq| 217
I ^
^^^ OT
CO
WASTE

00
H
CTl ,
339
ro
U9
(TV
V0
i— (
[R ST
LON1NG "*•"• ELEC
POT
26
H
"S1
i-H
Of
^H
n
H
IT
•U
O

t^
o
r-f
EAM COOLING AND BOILER PEED
FRIG -*| CONDENSING -. AND SANITARY *•
«ER
270

-------
FIGURE 3.  SCHEMATIC OF INDUSTRIAL WATER UTILIZATION  (CHEMICAL & ALLIED PRODUCTS - 28) 1968
FIGURE H.  SCHB-1ATIC OF INDUSTRIAL WATER  UTILIZATION  (PAPER 8 ALLIED PRODUCTS - 26) 1958
                                             10

-------
                FIGURE 5,   SCHEMATIC OF INDUSTRIAL WATER UTILIZATION CLUMBER & WOOD PRODUCTS   21)  1968
LOSSES
I FRESH WATER CO. SYSTEMS
         Once-through
            users
      ' 1  IrnnT.THnl -,  i
         Is COND.r
                                                                   FRESH WATER
                                                                 PUBLIC SYSTEMS
                                  22
                                       J           L
                                                                                                     BRACKISH WATER
                                           INTAKE .WATER TREATMENT
                                                                         67
                                             Recirculating Users
                              PROCESS
                               WATER
                             16
              14
                                     60
     AIR
CONDITIONING
                            WASTE WATER
                             TREATMENT
              31
                                                       141
                                    n
 STEAM
ELECTRIC
 POWER
   PUBLIC
  UTILITY
   SEWERS
COOLING AND
 CONDENSING
                                          SURFACE
                                         WATER BODY
       TIDEWATER
          BODY
       TO OTHER
        ' USERS
 BOILER FEED
AND SANITARY
h
      GROUND
      ' WATER
             FIGURE 6.   SCHEMATIC OF INDUSTRIAL WATER UTILIZATION (TEXTILE MILL PRODUCTS - 22)  1968
                                                              11

-------
FIGURE 7,   SCHEMATIC OF INDUSTRIAL WATER UTILIZATION (FOOD & KINDRED  PRODUCTS   20) 1968
                                             RIAL HATEBjTiLizATioN
                                             12

-------
          Table 3.  Nuclear Electric Power Plants


                         1968      1970    1972   1975   1980

No. of units              10        17        38     83     134
Installed Capacity, mw 2,759(1)  7,532(1) 20,667 61,518 112,662
Generation, 109 kwh     14.0(1)   23.8(1)   -       -
Plant Factor, %           58        36

AEC News Release July 26, 1972 unless noted
(1) 1971 Statistical Abstract of U. S.
Plant capacities and power generation are projected in
Table 4 on the basis of the above data, assuming plant
factors for nuclear plants of 50% in 1972, in 1975, and
60% in 1980 and for fossil-fueled plants of 55% in 1972,
56% in 1975, and 58% in 1980.
Table 4.  Projected Electric Power Plant Capacity and
                    Generation
                          1968     1972     1975     1980

Fossil-Fueled Plants:

  Installed Capacity, mw 226,020  291,718  342,080  426,018
  Generation, 109 kwh    1,072.9  1,405.5  1,678.1  2,164.5
  Plant Factor, %             54       55       56       58

Nuclear Plants:

  Installed Capacity, mw   2,759   20,667   61,518  112,662
  Generation, 109 kwh       14.0     90.5    296.4    592.2
  Plant Factor, %             58       50       55       60

Total Thermal Plants:

  Installed Capacity, mw 228,779  312,385  403,598  538,680
  Generation, 109 kwh    1,086.9  1,496.0  1,974.5  2,756.7
  Plant Factor, %             54       55       56       58

Water use and production data are not available for com-
parable years so that these data had to be estimated.

In 1964, the electric power industry took in 40,680 billion
gallons of water for cooling  (FWPCA, Industrial Waste Guide
on Thermal Pollution, September, 1968).  Of the 1,158
billion kwh produced in 1965, 1,055 billion kwh was pro-
duced by electric utilities, of which 81.6% or 861 billion
                           13

-------
kwh was produced in thermal-electric plants.   The installed
capacity in these thermal-electric plants was 192,000 mw.
On the basis of the 1960 installed thermal-electric capa-
city of 136,000 mw, and generation of 608 billion kwh, the
following is estimated for 1964, when about 13 percent of
cooling water was recirculated.
   Cooling water intake
   Cooling water use
   Installed capacity, mw
   Generation, billion kwh
               40,680 billion gallons
               45,968 billion gallons
              181,000 mw
                  810 billion kwh
Water use in 1964 was thus 56.75 gallon per kwh, of which
50.2 gallon per kwh was discharged.   In 1964 the average
rejection to cooling water was 5,480 BTU per kwh (FWPCA,
ibid), so that the average heat rise was 11.6°F.  These
data may be taken as representative  of 1968 practice.

A typical nuclear plant such as the  Quad Cities plant of
Commonwealth Edison, discharges 1.44 billion gallons of
water per day during on-line generation with an average heat
rise of 23°F; this plant has an installed capacity of
1,600 mw.  The  water use is thus 37.5 gallon per kwh with
a heat rejection of 7,185 BTU/kwh.

These data represent thermal efficiencies of 32.6 percent
and 30.6 percent for fossil-fueled and nuclear plants,
respectively.

Fossil fuel plants have an upper limit of thermal efficiency
of 40 percent while that of presently planned nuclear plants
is 33 percent.  The following projections assume efficiencies
with corresponding heat rejections:
                  Nuclear Plants
                  Fossil-Fueled Plants
                Efficiency BTU/kwh   Efficiency BTU/kwh
1968
1972
1975
1980
30.0
30.6
31.8
33.0
7,395
7,185
6,783
6,400
33. 0
35.3
37.1
40-0
5,378
4,806
4,406
3,800
Cooling water uses are assumed at 56.75 gallon per kwh for
fossil-fueled plants as in 1968 with 13 percent recircula-
tion and at 37.5 gallon per kwh for nuclear plants, used
once-through.  These would presumably be the water use
practices in the absence of pollution abatement require-
ments.  The electric power industry data developed are
summarized in Table 5.
                          14

-------
                      Table 5.   Projected Electric  Power  Industry Waste Loads
                                               Nuclear           Fossil           Total
                                               Plants            Plants          Thermal
1968:
  Installed Capacity, mw                        2,759            226,020           228,770
  Generation, 109 kwh  „                         14.0            1,072.9           1,086.9
  Cooling Water Use, 10  gallon                   525             60,887            61,412
  Cooling Water Discharge, 10  gallon             525             53,860            54,385
  BTU Discharge, 1012 BTU                         104              5,104             5,208


1972:

  Installed Capacity, mw                       20,667            291,718           312,385
  Generation, 109 kwh                            90.5            1,405.5           1,496.0
  Cooling Water Use, 109 gallon                 3,394             79,762            83,156
  Cooling water Discharge, 109 gallon           3,394             70,556            73,950
  3TU Discharge, 1012 BTU                         650              5,975             6,625


1975:

  Installed Capacity, mw                       61,518            342,080           403,598
  Generation, 109 kwh                           296.4            1,678.1           1,974.5
  Cooling Water Use, 109 gallon                11,115             95,232           106,347
  Cooling Water Discharge, 109 gallon          11,115             84,241            95,355
  BTU Discharge, 1012 BTU                       2,010              6,540             8,550


1980:

  Installed Capacity, mw                      112,662            426,018           538,680
  Generation, 109 kwh   Q                        592.2            2,154.5           2,756.7
  Cooling Water Use, 10  gallon                22,208            122,835           145,043
  Cooling Water Discharge, 109 gallon          22,208            108,658           130,866
  BTU Discharge, 1012 BTU                       3,790              7,276            11,066
                                      15

-------
                         SECTION V

       ALTERNATIVE DEFINITIONS OF MINIMUM DISCHARGE

A definition of minimum discharge is not as simple as it
may first appear.  The volumes of water discharged, if any,
will depend primarily upon the technology available and
upon the cost involved.  The availability of technology
largely determines the possibility of implementation; the
costs to be incurred as balanced against the benefits to
be derived determine the desirability of implementation
to a large extent.  Other determinants are the impacts on
the land and air environments and availability of resources.
First approximations were thus made of the order-of-mag-
nitude costs of implementing "minimum discharge" under
four different definitions.

Zero discharge, in a strictly literal sense, would pro-
bably involve the evaporation of waste water to dryness,
the condensation of evaporated water for recycle to the
plant, and the discharge of the resulting solid wastes
underground.  Even in this case, the heat rejected in the
vapor condensation would go to either the air or water
environments.

If an initial qualification is imposed that thermal pollu-
tion from the manufacturing industries will not be consid-
ered, then the volume of process waste water discharged,
assuming segregation  of uncontaminated cooling water,
determines the treatment needs.

If a further qualification is made that only the contaminants
in waste water generated by manufacturing operations are to
be considered, the treatment needs are still further reduced.
A further qualification might be considered to the effect
that neutral salts would not be regarded as significant
pollutant materials, i.e., that the criteria applying to
total dissolved solids may be modified.

These definitions may be stated as follows; they are
illustrated schematically in Figures 9 through 12 and
summarized in Table 6.

Definition No. 1  (Figure 9): Zero discharge is defined as
the discharge of no liquid effluent from an industrial
operation and the storage underground of all solid residues.

Definition No. 2  (Figure 10); Minimum practicable discharge
is defined as the discharge of no liquid effluent from an
industrial operation, other than uncontaminated cooling
water from plants with effluent heat loads of less than
                           17

-------
                             Table 6.   Definitions of Minimum Discharge
          Water Use
                            Allowable
                            Discharge
                                                                                  Remarks
Definition I (Strict Interpretation)

   Cooling

   Industrial Plants
     <20 x 1012 3TU/Yr

   Indu3trial Plants
    >20 x 1012 BTU/Yr

   Steam Electric
   Process
                             None
                             Nona
                             None
                                                              Hecirculatior. with all
                                                              blowdown distilled and
                                                              injected in deep wells
Definition II
   Ind.  <20 x 10
                 12
   Ind.  >20 x 10
   Electric
   Process
                 12
                             Heat and dissolved
                             salts 0  Intaka  -t-62
                             None
                             None
                             None
                                 6% increase in concen-
                                 tration covers
                                 existing recirculation
                                 @ isolated plants

                                 Recirculation with blowdown
                                 distilled and injected
                                 to deep wells
Definition III
   Ind.   <20 x 10

   Ind.   >20 x 10
   Steam Electric
                 12
12
   Process
Heat and intake
Dissolved Solids
Intake Dissolved
Salts
                                             No:ie
Definition IV (Currently Used - State  of  Illinois)
Intake solids only - no
concentration limit
Intake solids contained
in cooling tower blow-
down only - no concentra-
tion limit
Recirculation witn
blowdown distilled and
injected to deep wells
   Ind.   <20 x 10
   Ind.   >20 x 10
   Steam Electric
   Process
12
12
Heat and Dissolved Solids
Dissolved Solids
Dissolved Solids
Dissolved Solids
                                                                              Treatment  to allow
                                                                              discharge  to  (i)  sur-
                                                                              face waters  (ii)
                                                                              municipal  plants  (iii)
                                                                              deep wells
                                          18

-------
I
SURFACE WATER SUPPLY
                                  PROCESS WATER
                                      OSES
                                  TERMINAL
                                  TREATMENT
                                  COOLING
                                   TOWERS
                                               SOLIDS
                                              DISPOSAL
                            COOLING WATER
                                USES
                                                                           COOLING
                                                                            TOWERS
                               DISSOLVED
                                 SOLIDS
                             CONCENTRATION
                                                                                               BOILER FEED
                                                                                               AND OTHER.
            FIGURE 9.  DEFINITION NO. 1- ZERO LIQUID DISCHARGE WITH  UNDERGROUND  STORAGE  OF  SOLIDS
                                            SURFACE WATER SUPPLY
                      PROCESS WATER
                          USES
                           1
                        TERMINAL
                        TREATMENT
                         COOLING
                          TOWERS
TS O
rt oi
a 01
-p *&
a
ID ID
ta A:
  ra
  a
  •H
        COOLING WATER
            USES
         <20xl012BTU/yr,
                                                    BOILER FEED
                                                     AND OTHER
                                                     DISSOLVED
                                                        SOLIDS
                                                   CONCENTRATION
COOLING WATER
    USES
                                       COOLING
                                        TOWERS
                                                                               SOLIDS
                                                                              DISPOSAL
     FIGURE 10.   DEFINITION NO. 2- DISCHARGE DULY HEAT AND DISSOLVED  SOLIDS AT INTAKE CONCENTRATIONS (+6%)
                                                         19

-------
                             SURFACE WATER SUPPLY
    PROCESS WATER
        USES
       TERMINAL
       TREATMENT
  COOLING WATER
 USES-HEAT LOADS

<20 X 1012 BTU/yi
 COOLING WATER
USES-HEAT LOADS
                                                           >20 x 1012 BTU/yr
                                   COOLING TOWERS
       COOLING
       TOWERS
                                                                 COOLING
                                                                 TOWERS
                           BOILER FEED
                            AND OTHER
                             DISSOLVED
                              SOLIDS
                           CONCENTRATION
                              SOLIDS
                             DISPOSAL
                                         (	)  Alternative Uses
FIGURE 11.   DEFINITION NO.  3- DISCHARGE ONLY HEAT AND INTAKE DISSOLVED SOLIDS
                            SURFACE WATER SUPPLY
| Intake and Process Dissolved Solids; others at Stream stdl

PROCESS WATER
*" USES
i
'*
TERMINAL
TREATMENT
I

COOLING

.....
| CONTRO
1 	

__ Heat and intake^ I
•»-
T3 01
0)13
S> -H II
•H H
™ COOLING WAt
0 USES -HEAT L(
<20X10J''! BTl
•» | COOLING TO!
1 	
BOILER FEED
AND OTHER
\
LLED | I
RGB | I
	 J I
1 I
SOLIDS i
DISPOSAL J (
i
CER -H
3ADS 0
VI
J/yr |
U LJLI
2 1
2 S Intake and Process DLSSO
" | TR1
1 I
L _.
	 ) Alterr
0}
*)
c
-H
i i "O
C
	 ^ BB^ ffl
COOLING WATER -g
T3 USES -HEAT LOADS d)
^ ^a— S
fl >20 x 10^ BTU/yr ^ (
ID
01
^ ' '
4J
rt COOLING
„ TOWERS ~ 	 ^
M
(II
JJ
O
IICIPAL |
MAGE ' MUNICIPAL
ATMENT *"* 	 SEWAGE
>LANT 1
™ « • J ~-
Dissolved Solids 1
lative Uses/Treatment/Disposal
   FIGURE 12,  DEFINITION NO. 1- DISCHARGE ONLY HEAT AND DISSOLVED  SOLIDS
                                        20

-------
       12  '
20 x 10   BTU per year which differs from  intake water
quality only in temperature and dissolved  solids, and
the storage underground of all solid residues.

Definition No. 3  (Figure 11):  Minimum practicable dis-
charge = is defined as the discharge of no liquid effluent
from an industrial operation other than water used for
indirect cooling in plants where the effluent heat load
is less than 20 x 1012 BTU per year and blowdown from
indirect cooling uses containing no contaminants generated
by the industrial operation other than heat and the
storage underground of all solid residues.

Definition No. 4  (Figure12);  Minimum practicable
discharge  is defined as the discharge of no liquid effluent
from an industrial operation other than water used for
indirect cooling in plants where the effluent heat load
is less than 20 x lO12 BTU per year, and blowdown from
indirect cooling uses containing no contaminants genera-
ted by the industrial operation other than  heat, and the
disposal of minimum waste water volumes containing mini-
mum concentrations of contaminants other than dissolved
solids, by means including co-treatment in municipal
sewage treatment plants.

The order-of-magnitude costs of implementing regulations
based upon these various definitions were  initially
estimated  from gross water use data in the manufacturing
and electric power industries for the year 1968.  The basic
assumptions were that water vould be internally recircu-
lated to the greatest possible extent and  that the blow-
down from  the recirculation systems would  be evaporated
to produce a lower volume brine.  The brine would then be
disposed of by deepwell injection where the definition
so required.  These initially estimated costs are shown
in Table 7.
              Table  7.  Iiitial Cost Estimated
                          Costs  in Billions of 1968 Dollars
Definition               Capital Costs  Annual Operating Costs

Terminal Treatment            4.000            0.708
No. 4                         7.254            1.198
No. 3                        12.286            1.886
No. 2                        13.746            2.102
No. 1                        19.500            3.192
                            21

-------
                        SECTION VI

                   DEFINITIONS OF COSTS

Definitions of costs vary considerably when evaluated by
economists, accountants, cost accountants, or engineers.
The background and training, to say nothing of the
motivations of the people in these disciplines, are
different.  Profits to accountants, cost accountants,
and engineers are synonymous with net income, i.e., the
residual after subtracting outgo from income.  Profits
in the lay definition,include tfie return to all factors
of production without differentiation.  To the economist,
profit is specifically the return to entrepreneurial
ability and, by definition, accrues only to the super-
marginal enterprise.  Rent, similarly, is the return to
land, again by definition accruing only to super-marginal
land.  Interest is the return to capital  (only super-
ficially the charge made for loaned funds) and wages are
the return to labor  (including management).

Much more insight into the factors affecting costs could
be gained from at least considering the economist's
definitions rather than the accountant's or financier's
simplistic conceptions.  Taking, for example, two steel
mills, one might compare the costs of implementing'zero
waste water discharge.  The first is an integrated steel
mill with a capacity of about 1.5 million ingot tons per
year.  The other operates an electric furnace shop some
distance away which has about the same capacity.  The former
has agreed to install terminal treatment facilities which
will discharge water of better quality than required for
in-plant use and is resisting to the point of litigation
the reuse of this water with blowdown to a sanitary sewer.
The latter began the installation of a zero discharge
system 10 years ago and has recently completed it.  The
second is a closely-held corporation and the rate of return
is not known, but is reportedly high for the industry.
Overhead, as reflected in office buildings, furnishings,
etc., is obviously low; there are none of the usual executive
trappings in offices and the plant engineer designed the
water reuse system in-house.  This mill has two electric
furnaces, both of which have air pollution control levels
which exceed emission standards and incorporate closed-cycle
use of water in venturi scrubbers.  Building evacuation hoods
were built voluntarily when the State suggested it; there
is no specific legal requirement for such installations.

The former company is one of the large integrated steel
producers and the example plant is only one of its smaller
plants.  While this mill is an integrated facility, i.e.,
                           23

-------
 has  a  coke  plant  and blast  furnace,  it  is, however,  fair
 to compare  the  steelmaking  and  rolling  mill  facilities
 alone  with  the  second.   The conclusion  is inescapable that
 there  are differences  in the philosophy and  attitudes
 toward pollution  control which  are interestingly  related
 to differences  in production philosophies and methods.
 It is  suggested that the differences may well lie in the
 realm  of entrepreneurial ability, i.e.,  in innovation and
 foresight,  and  in the  factor of rent, i.e.,  the return  to
 the  use of  land.  Costs,  as reflected in interest and wages
 might  be presumed to be  about equal  for similar size steel
 plants in the same  general  area; there  is at least the
 suspicion,  however, that wages  in the form of more manage-
 ment and other  overhead  labor may well  be greater in the
 case of the multi-plant  firm as allocated to this facility.

 While  it is probably not practical to attempt to  quantify
 such factors, and is certainly  not possible  without  data
 that would  not  be readily available  to  outsiders,  these
 factors should  at least  be  born in mind when considering
 relative costs.   Costs which were reportedly about equal in
 terms  of capital  investment in  these two similar  instances
 certainly produced  different results.   More  per dollar  spent
•was  realized in one case than in the other and the explana-
 tion requires more  than  a superficial look at dollar amounts.

 Leaving philosophy  aside, at least for  a time, costs must,
 in practice, be based  upon  data which can be obtained or
 reasonably  estimated.  There are many factors which  must be
 defined in  formulating costs, particularly when costs are
 to be  annualized.   Compromises  must be  made  between  strict
 economic definitions and those  which are, in practice,
 affected by accounting conventions,  tax laws, etc.   These
 factors are discussed below.

 Economic; Life

 The  economic life of a facility installed for pollution
 abatement purposes  can hardly exceed that of the  production
 facilities  which  it serves.  A  reasonable working definition
 would  appear to be  the useful life of the pollution  abatement
 equipment alone or  the useful life of the related production
 facilities, whichever  is shorter.  Annualized capital costs
 would  thus  be the initial capital cost  plus  capitalized
 repairs over the  useful  economic life,  less  the salvage value.
 The  useful  economic life of a production facility may be taken
 to be  tne asset guideline period as  established by the
 Internal Revenue  Service, examples of which  are shown in
 Table  8.  The useful economic lives  of  some  specific pieces
 of equipment which  might together constitute a pollution
 control facility  are illustrated in  Table 9.
                          24

-------
         Table  8.  Asset Guideline Periods  as  Established  by  the Internal Revenue Service
                                                          Asset Depreciation
                                                            Range  (in years)
Asset
Guide-
line
Class
13.3
20.4
21.0

22.2
24.4


Description of Assets
Petroleum refining
All other food and kindred products
Manufacture of tobacco and tobacco
products
Textile mill products, except knitwear
Manufacture of lumber and wood products

Lower
Limit
13
9.5

12
11

Asset
Guide-
line
Period
16
12

15
14


Upper
Limit
19
14.5

18
17

Annual Asset
Guideline
Repair
Allowance
Percentage
7.0
5.5

5.0
4.5

          and furniture
26.1     Manufacture of pulps from wood and other
          cellulose fibers and rags
28.0     Manufacture of chemicals and allied
          products
30.1     Manufacture of rubber products
32.1     Manufacture of glass products
33.1     Ferrous metals
33.2     Konferrous metals
39.0     Manufacture of products not elsewhere
          classified
49.11    Hydraulic production plant
49.12    Nuclear production plant
49.13    Stean Production plant
49-3     Water utilities
13
 9.5
40
16
22.5
40
                                                                 10
       16
 9     11
11     14
11     14
14.5   18
11     14
12
50
20
28
50
12

19

13
17
17
21.5
17

14.5
60
24
33.5
60
6.5

4.5

5.5
5.0
6.0
8.0
4.5

5.5
1.5
3.0
2.0
1.5
                                           25

-------
Table 9.  Estimated Depreciation Rates for Buildings
                  and Equipment
Equipment or Building                       Annual Percent
Blowers                                           7
Buildings
  Mill Construction                               4
  Corrugated Iron                                10

Plumbing
  Sewer and drainage pipe                         6
  Drainage tile                                   2

Compressors                                       5

Condensers
  Steam (atmosphere)                              4
  Steam (surface)                                 5

Dust Collector Equipment                          5

Filters
  Vacuum continuous                              10

Furniture and fixtures                           10

Laboratory equipment                              7

Motors                                         5-10

Piping
  Wrought iron                                    3
  Cast iron, 8 in. and larger                     1 1/2
  Steam                                           5

Pumps
  Centrifugal                                     5
  Rotary                                          5
  Direct acting                                   4

Tanks
  Concrete                                        2
  Steel                                           5
                          26

-------
A factor of potential importance in evaluating  and  comparing
capital costs is the choice of materials of  construction,
i.e., the choice between long-lived,  corrosion  resistant
materials and short-lived materials which  are less  expen-
sive and may or may not entail increased maintenance costs.
Kaiser Steel Corporation, for example, has long adopted
the practice of using carbon steel piping, etc.  almost
exclusively and expecting short-lived performance as opposed
to using initially more expensive materials.  Ceramic
cooling towers, for another example,  last  longer than wooden
towers and are virtually maintenance-free, but  cost about
twice as much as wooden towers.

According to an Internal Revenue Service engineer,  three
alternatives are open to industry in  depreciating pollution
control facilities :

     1.  A five-year write-off if the facilities qualify
     under state and federal law relating  specifically to
     pollution control facilities.

     2.  Write-off at the rate of production facilities.

     3.  Write-off at a slower rate if it  can be shown
     that the specific equipment will have some other use-
     ful life.

According to this engineer, most industries write off pollution
control facilities at the same rate as production facilities.
An interesting comment was that many  industries, particularly
electric utilities, attempt to classify as much equipment as
possible as pollution abatement facilities for  the  public
relations effects.

Cost of Capital  (Money)

Insofar as debt capital is concerned, the  cost  is at least
the  interest rate on borrowed funds.  This rate will generally
be the prime rate  for large, financially sound  corporations.
For  smaller corporations or sole proprietors, the interest
rate will be higher, particularly if  the operation  is finan-
cially marginal.   In some cases of very small,  marginal enter-
prices, the interest rate may be the  personal loan  rate to
the owner.

The  cost of equity capital will generally  be the opportunity
cost, i.e., the rate of return that would  be realized^if an
investment had been made in alternative income-producing.
This, on the average, would be equal  to the  rate of return in
the  industry considered, but opportunities in diversification
should probably be considered.
                           27

-------
When borrowing capacity is limited, the cost of debt capital
is the opportunity cost, assuming that funds borrowed for
pollution control facilities would have been invested in
income production and are unavailable for such purposes.
Industrial revenue bonds offer a means by which financing
can be obtained which presumably does not affect borrowing
capacity for other purposes.  Such bonds have been authorized
in all states except California, Idaho, New Jersey and Texas
and must bear a minimum interest rate of 6 percent, which
is tax free since the issuing agency is usually a municipal
or county government.  Since such bonds sell at about 2
percent less than the rate for corporate debentures, the
difference is still an overall cost in the sense of taxes
foregone.  A fifteen-year term is about average.  An under-
writing fee of 1 percent of the value of the issue is
generally charged.

The costs of capital thus seem logically to be the opportunity
costs in each industry, or the interest rate on borrowed
funds, including bonds, if financing is such that borrowing
for income-production is not impaired.

Definitions of Pollution Abatement Facilities

Accelerated depreciation of pollution control facilities or
qualifications for industrial revenue bond financing requires
certification of state and federal agencies, including the
Internal Revenue Service.  Such definitions are not clear
cut when pollution control equipment serves a production func-
tion, but are straightforward for such items as gas scrubbers
and waste water treatment equipment.

Problems in definition can arise in separating the costs of
water-use facilities necessary for production even with once-
through use and no effluent restrictions in a given locality
from the costs of changes in water-use practices, production
modifications, and reuse facilities installed solely for
pollution abatement.  Additionally, there must be some
definition of increased production costs attributable to
pollution abatement methods.

In the cases of mill scale pits and flue dust clarifiers in
steel mills and ammonia stills and saturators in coke plants/
the annualized costs less credits for by-products probably
incorporate these distinctions, since the residual costs can
be fairly attributed to pollution abatement.
                          28

-------
In the case -of a mechanical debarker  installed  in  a  pulp
mill, it is not so clear as to  the  cost  attributable to
pollution abatement.  If shell  and  tube  condensers are
substituted for barometric condensers in an  oil  refinery,
the cost attributed to pollution  abatement is also not
clear.  In both cases, waste water  is eliminated.

When one steel mill has recirculated  water because it had
no adequate supply and another  recirculated  water  for
pollution abatement in the face of  an unlimited  supply,
and both achieve the  same degree  of pollution abatement,
determining the costs of pollution  abatement is  not  clear
cut.

Perhaps a general solution would  be to base  all  costs on
the once-through use  of water of  average industry  rates
per unit of production and attribute  all costs which reduce
effluent contaminant  loads and/or volumes to pollution
abatement irrespective of the motivation.  To the  extent,
then that some costs  are clearly  overstated, suitable adjust-
ments could be made.  Errors would, at least, be consis-
tently on the high side.  Internal  Revenue Service opinions
will probably provide a basis eventually, but they are
currently few in number and appear  very  slowly.

Bases oi: Cost Comparisons

To be meaningful, costs must be related  to some  measures
of business volume, profitability,  etc.  such as  sales, net
income, equity, or other parameters.   The capital  costs of
pollution abatement facilities  as related to the value of
production facilities is probably the most realistic basis
upon which to compare the former.   Expressing the  cost of
pollution abatement facilities  as a fraction of  the  original
cost of the production facilities,  both  in constant  or cur-
rent dollars, is the  only consistent  way to  make such a
comparison.  The use  of depreciated values leads to  highly
variable and fallacious expressions of costs, making compari-
sons meaningless unless the bases of  calculations  are
precisely defined.

If the capital costs'of a new treatment  facility are, for
example, expressed as a ratio of  the  costs of depreciated
production facilities in terms  of original price,  a  very
high ratio results.   If such cost comparisons are  made in new
installations when depreciation rates of treatment and pro-
duction facilities are taken to be  different, such ratios
will again vary from  case to case.  At the limit,  the ratio
of the value of new treatment facilities to  fully  depreciated
production facilities would be  infinite. At least passing
consideration must be given to  such expressions  of investment;
                          29

-------
it seems probable that some of the variations in reported
ratios of investment in pollution abatement are due to the
use of various of these methods of calculation.
                  *

The annualized capital costs of pollution abatement
facilities as related to the annualized capital costs of
the production facilities served, both expressed in con-
stant dollars, seems to be clearly the most logical basis
for comparative purposes, assuming that the economic lives
and costs of capital can be satisfactorily expressed.  The
definition of a comparative base for operating costs pre-
sents, at least initially, several alternatives.

Since operating costs are, by definition, annualized costs,
they are directly relatable to income, expenditures,,etc.
per unit period of time.  Possible comparative bases are
thus :

     1.  Annual sales

     2.  Annual net income

     3.  Annual return on sales

     4.  Annual return on equity

     5.  Annual value added
                          r
The base upon which the costs of pollution abatement
facilities are compared should be selected so as to impart
some item of information relative to economic effects.  The
extent to which such costs will cause economic dislocations
by reducing production, resulting in unemployment, or
reducing income to the factors of production would seem to
be those of interest insofar as the cost side of the economic
ledger is concerned.  At least for the present, the economic
benefits of more stringent pollution abatement requirements
will not be considered.  The former, however, should be
measured so as to be comparable with the latter.

Given that potentially adverse economic effects are to be
measured and that a consistent basis should be used for future
comparisons with beneficial effects, the National Income and
Gross National Product data seem to provide the best bases.
Macroeconomic statistics can thus be used for the assessment
of general effects and used as comparative bases for studies
of regional and single plant effects.  Such data are appli-
cable and separable for comparing capital and operating costs.
Their use in business cycle analysis would also seem to indi-
cate a specific utility here.  The ready availability of
such data from a government agency and general acceptability
are, of course, important considerations.
                          30

-------
The expression of the capital costs of pollution abatement
as related to Gross Private Domestic  Investment is consis-
tent with the previously given measure as  a  fraction of
investment in production facilities.  Operating costs as
related to annual net income and  to value  added in the
aggregate can be readily determined from these data.
Relationships of operating costs  to sales, return on sales,
and return on equity can be determined for industry groups
from ancillary data published by  the  Department of Com-
merce.  The latter comparative data can also be reduced to
at least the corporation unit through annual report data.
Reduction of comparative data to  the  individual plant or
other production unit basis cannot generally be done out-
side of the firm, except by estimation.

Capital Costs

Waste water treatment facilities  are  generally similar to
chemical process equipment and it is  thus  logical to use
chemical engineering estimating techniques in evaluating
the cost of such facilities.  Guthrie's module cost techni-
que  (18) seems particularly appropriate, since it provides
some insight into the various cost components and data in
this form are available on the basis  of considerable
experience.

On the basis of a typical chemical process project on a
Gulf Coast  job site in mid 1968,  the  cost  components shown
in Table 10 are regarded as typical:
              Table 10.   Capital Cost Components


                              Relative Cost Percent of  Cost

 F.O.B.  cost  of equipment             100.0          28.72
 Direct  field materials:                62.2          17.86
   Piping                       (32.0)         (9.19)
   Other                       (30.2)         (8.67)
 Direct  field labor                    58.0          16.66
 Indirect  costs:                      128.0          36.76
   Freight, insurance,  taxes   (13.7)         (3.93)
   Construction overhead       (39.2)        (11.26)
   Engineering                 (22.0)         (6.32
   Contingency                  (8.9)         (2.56)
   Contractor fee              (44.2)        (12.69)
                                      348.2         100.00
                          31

-------
Operating; Costs

Operating costs may be formulated from consideration of the
typical items of cost in the case of a good manufactured
for sale.  Considering the nature of pollution abatement
facilities, the internal cost to the firm may be expressed
as shown in Table 11, eliminating packaging and shipping,
sales, etc., and depreciation, since the latter is
included in annualized capital costs in the present
analysis:


        Table 11.  Components of Operating Costs
   I.  Manufacturing Cos,ts

       A.  Chemicals
       B.  Labor and Supervision
       C.  Maintenance and Supplies
       D.  Power and Utilities
       E.  Royalties and Patents
       F.  Payroll and Plant Overhead
       G.  Laboratory
       H.  Property Taxes and Insurance

  II.  General Expense

       A.  Administration
       B.  Research
       C.  Interest on Working Capital
       D.  Total

 III.  Total Cost

       A.  Manufacturing Cost
       B.  General Expense
       C.  Subtotal
       D.  By-product Credits
       E.  Income Tax Credits
       F.  Total Credits
       G.  Net Cost
These items, of course, refer to the allocations to waste
water treatment facilities, including reuse systems to the
extent installed for purposes of pollution abatement.
                         32

-------
Insofar as the concept of maximum water  reuse prior,to dis-
posal of a residual is involved  in  implementing  "zero dis-
charge", the costs of pollution  abatement become analagous
to the costs of water utilization.   The  components of the
latter costs, at any rate, would be expected to  be propor-
tionately the same, eliminating  purchased water  as a cost
item.
      Table 12.  Total Costs of  Industrial Water Use


                           Daily  Costs  in  Dollars  (1969)
Cost Item             Steel     Paper   Petroleum Chemical Total

Raw Materials         8,794     3,932    12,377   4,484   29,587
Labor                 7,280    11,039     8,818   3,799   30,936
Maintenance  & Power   7,984     7,650    67,721   3,134   86,489
Payroll Overhead      1,820     2,760-    2,205     953    7,738
Plant Overhead        3,650     5,519     4,409   1,907   15,485
Depreciation        30,241    12,073   505,276  12,327  559,917
Property taxes  &
 insurance              606       241    10,106     246   11,199
Total                60,375    43,214   610,912  26,850  741,351
 "Raw materials"  in  the  above  items  includes purchased water;
 chemicals  for  treatment account for the  relative portions of
 this cost  item shown  in Table 13.   (CEP,  Symposium Series,
 65, No.  97,  1969) :
         Table  13.   Water Use  Cost Components
                	Relative  Costs	
 Industry        Purchased Water  Chemicals    %  for Chemicals
                %  of  Daily Cost % of  Daily Cost
 Steel                16.3          5.6            25.6
 Paper                 0.0          6.7            100.0
 Petroleum             0.3          0.7            70.0
 Power                 1.0          1.0           ,50.0


 Using the  above percentages  to estimate  the  chemical  costs,
 assuming that  the chemical .industry  percentage  is about^the
 average.in the steel and petroleum industries,  and elimina-
 ting depreciation, the  manufacturing cost components  are as
 shown in Table 14.
                          33

-------
       Table 14.  Water Use Costs Less Depreciation
Cost^Item

Chemicals
Labor
Maintenance and Power
Payroll Overhead
Plant Overhead
Property Taxes and
 insurance
Total

Water used, mgd
                       Steel
Daily Costs in Dollars (1969)	
    Paper Petroleum Chemical Total
2,251
7,280
7,984
1,820
3,650
3,932
11,039
7,650
2,760
5,519
8,664
8,818
67,721
2,205
4,409
2,242
3,799
3,134
953
1,907
17,089
30,936
86,489
7,738
15,485
                         606     241   10,106     246   11,199
                      23,591  31,141  101,923  12,281  168,936

                      1509.6   835.8   5507.5   664.8   8517.7
The above data were used to determine average weighted
percentage contributions of these cost components and,
together with average relative costs in the chemical process
industries for other items as taken from Aries and Newton,
yielded the operating cost formulation as in Table 15.
       Table 15.   Average Operating Cost Components
  I.  Manufacturing Costs: '

      A.  Chemicals
      B.  Labor and Supervision
      C.  Maintenance and Power
      D.  Royalties and Patents (0.01 x III.C)  =
      E.  Payroll and Plant Overhead
      F.  Laboratory           (0.20 x I.E. )  =
      G.  Property Taxes and Insurance
      H.  Total

 II.  General Expense:

      A.  Administration        (0.06 x I.H) =
      B.  Research              (0.10 x I.H) =
      C.  Interest on Working Capital (0.08 x III.C)
      D.  Total

III.  Total Cost:

      A.  Manufacturing
      B.  General Expense
      C.  Subtotal
      D.  By-product Credits
      E.  Income Tax Credits
      F.  Total Credits
      G.  Net Cost
                                                        .098
                                                        .170
                                                        .533
                                                       0.013
                                                        .128
                                                        .034
                                                        .071
                                                       1.047
                                                       0.063
                                                       0.105
                                                       0.106
                                                       0.274
                                                       1.047
                                                       0.274
                                                       1.321
                          34

-------
                        SECTION VII

        AVAILABLE TECHNOLOGY FOR MINIMUM DISCHARGE

The technology required for minimum discharge may be
grouped as follows:

     1.  Methods to reduce water use

     2.  Methods to treat water for reuse

     3.  Methods to recirculate water

     4.  Methods to reduce residual waste water volumes

     5.  Methods for ultimate disposal of minimum residuals

The distinction between water use and water discharge
or intake must be borne in mind.  It has been a quite general
assumption that water use in the steel industry, for example,
averages about 40,000 gallons per ton of finished steel and
about  30,000 gallons per ton of raw steel.  The data on
Table  16 demonstrate the fact that the terms are used loosely
and incorrectly.  The above figures should have been stated
as water discharged or taken in per ton, not as the quantity
used.  Although the volume of water discharged per ton
dropped in the 9-year period, the volume of water used increased.
          Table  16.   Steel  Industry Water Use Data
                                  1959
1964
1968
 Steel Production,  1,000  tons:
   Raw Steel                  ,    93.446    127.076   131.462
   Finished Steel                 69.377     84.945     91.856

                  9
 Water Volumes,  10   gallons:
   Intake                           2994       3815       4071
   Discharge                        2876       3569       3811
   Used                             4571       5427       6154

 Water Volumes,  gal.  per  ton:
   Discharged:                     „                    nnnnn
     Raw Steel Basis               30800      28100      29000
     Finished Steel Basis         41500      42000      41500
   Used:
     Raw Steel Basis               48900      42700      46800
     Finished Steel Basis         65900      63900      67000
                          35

-------
Methods to reduce water use, therefore/ do not include
cooling towers/ for example/ as many writers have at least
tacitly assumed.  Neither are such processes as electro-
dialysis, reverse osmosis/ ion exchange, etc. properly
considered effluent treatments for the purposes of this
study, since they produce a clean stream and a concen-
trated stream, which, taken together, still contain the
original (or even greater) amounts of contaminants; they
are classified here as waste water volume reduction methods.
Examples of technology for particular purposes are as
follows:

     1.  Methods to reduce water use:
         a.  Electrostatic precipitators (vs. wet scrubbers)
             for air pollution control
         b.  Bag houses (vs. wet scrubbers)  for air pollution
             control
         c.  Evaporation chambers (vs. spray towers)  in
             air control
         d.  Dry scale removal (vs.  flume flushing) in
             rolling mills
         e.  Savealls on paper machines
         f.  Long-log debarking in pulp mills
         g.  Water flows geared to production rates
         h.  Dry floor cleaning (vs. hosing)
         i.  Air coolers  (vs. water coolers)  in petroleum
             refineries
         j.  Surface condensers (vs. barometric condensers)
             in chemical plants
         k.  Process water sewers (vs. combined sewers)

     2.  Methods to treat water for reuse:
         a.  Cooling towers
         b.  Spray ponds or canals
         c.  Cooling ponds
         d.  Sedimentation
         e.  Sedimentation-flocculation
         f.  Chemical precipitation
         g.  Filtration
         h.  Oil separation
         i.  Chemical treatment

     3.  Methods to recirculate water:
         a.  Recirculation on paper machines
         b.  Sequential uses of water for progressively
             lower uses
         c.  Recirculation of flume water in rolling mills
         d.  At process recirculation systems
         e.  Diversion of treated effluents to present
             intake pumps
         f.  Diversion of treated effluents to new intake pumps
                         36

-------
     4.   Methods to reduce residual waste water volumes:
         a.   Evaporation or -distillation
         b.   Reverse osmosis
         c.   Electrodialysis
         d.   Ion exchange

     5.   Methods for ultimate disposal of minimum residuals:
         a.   Ocean disposal
         b.   So^.ar evaporation
         c.   Deep well disposal
         d.   Incineration
         e.   Landfill
         f.   Burial
         g.   Discharge to brackish water

For the purposes of this study, it has been assumed that
water use reductions beyond those currently in practice would
not be utilized and that water treatment for reuse would be
the same as that required currently for discharge with the
addition of cooling towers.  The method assumed for water
recirculation is the diversion of treated effluents to new
intake pumps and the provision of new distribution piping.
The method assumed for reducing residual waste water volumes
is evaporation.  The methods assumed for ultimate disposal
of minimum residuals are deepwell disposal, solar evaporation,
incineration, and ocean disposal to the extent each is
geographically possible.

These methods have been used in the study because they are
proven technology.  They are, together with the assumption
of no significant water use reductions, the high-cost alter-
natives in most cases.  On the basis of these assumptions,
the cost estimates should be on the high side, i.e., con-
servative in the sense of not understating costs.
                          37

-------
                       SECTION VIII

                RESIDUAL EFFLUENT DISPOSAL

The ultimate disposal of residual waste water, i.e., water
containing essentially only dissolved inorganic solids in
the minimum practicable volume from an industrial operation
could be accomplished by several methods with minimum
environmental impact.

Possible methods include:

     1.  Underground injection (deepwells)

     2.  Underground cavities

     3.  Spreading/landfill

     4.  Solar evaporation

     5.  Discharge to brackish water

     6.  Ocean discharge

Ocean Disposal

The applicability of the various methods is a function
largely of geographical location.  Based upon Koenig's
data for the costs of ultimate disposal of waste water
from Advanced Waste Treatment processes (WP-20-AWTR-19,
1968) , typical costs for disposal to the ocean are as shown
in Table 17, based upon a 30-mile ocean outfall and con-
veyed distances of 100 or 1,000 miles.  The costs for con-
veying 1,000 miles are based upon preconcentration by
evaporation.


         Table 17.  Total Costs for Ocean Disposal
Waste Water Volume, gpd
         500,000
       1,000,000
       5,000,000
      10,000,000
Costs per 1,000 gallons
100 miles   1,000 miles
 $ 1.84
   1.31
   0.72
   0.53
$ 2.76
  1.88
  1.84
  1.02
                          39

-------
 Koenig's data were optimized on the basis of the most
 advantageous conveyance (pipe or rail).   The operating
 costs for conveyance were segregated and the operating costs
 for distillation in the case of the 1,000-mile distance
 were taken from the inorganic Chemical Industry Profile data,

 Considering the costs of conveyance plus the costs of dis-
 tillation for the 1,000 miles distance as operating costs
 with the remainder as annualized capital costs, costs were
 calculated as in Table 18.
  Table 18.   Capital and Operating Costs of Ocean Disposal


             100 miles ($/1000 gal.)     1000 miles ($/10QQ gal)
              Operating  Annual Cap.    OperatingAnnual Cap.
 Volume, gpd    Costs      Costs         Costs      Costs

   500,000      1.00        0.84         1-52       1.24
 1,000,000      0.75        0.56         1.08       0.80
 5,000,000      0.44        0.28         1.1.2       0.72
10,000,000      0.29        0.24         0.75       0.27

 Deepwell Disposal

 For the case of a 100 mgd AWT plant  operating at 95 percent
 product water recovery,  Koenig calculated the cost of deep-
 well disposal at 0.9 cents per 1,000 gallon of product water.
 Such a plant would produce 95,000 x  10^ gpd of product water;
 daily costs would thus be $855 for the disposal of 5 mgd
 of waste water, or $0.171 per 1,000  gallons.  This is
 essentially the same cost as calculated by Rapier (Burns
 and Roe, Inc. FWQA Contract No. ,14-12-495 [17070 DJW] )  at a
 fixed charge rate of 10  percent; Rapier shows no difference
 in costs as a function of volume from 10 mgd to 1.0 mgd, but
 indicates a cost of $0.28 per 1,000  gallon at a daily volume
 of 100,000  gallons.

 Rapier's costs are based upon disposal wells 3,500 feet deep,
 30-year project life, electrical power at 12 mils per kwhr,
 and relatively low injection pressures.  A more likely basis
 for the present purpose  are the data in Inorganic Chemicals
 Indus try P r of ile based upon the work of Moseley and Malina
 relating specifically to industrial  waste disposal.  These
 data are based upon depths generally necessary to prevent
 groundwater contamination, 20-year project life, electrical
 power at $0.005 per kwhr, and up to  1,400 psi injection
 pressure, interest rates are taken at 5 percent.  Taking the
 interest rate at 10 percent, the injection pressure at
                          40

-------
1,000 psi, arid eliminating  depreciation,  operating costs
were calculated  as  shown  in Table 19.
            Table  19.   Deepwell Disposal Costs


                             Costs per 1,000 gal,  injected	
Daily J_Vol_ume             Ope rating Cos ts"AnnualizedCapital~"c6s"t

  100,000  gal.              $ 0.4644             $  0.6436
  500,000  gal.                0.2528                0.1512
1,000,000  gal.                0.2020                0.0853


Solar Evaporation

For  solar  evaporation plus disposal of brine at 100 mile
distance,  Rapier's data for ponds and Koenig's data for
100  mile conveyance after concentration yield the following
data shown in Table 20.


Table 20.   Costs of Solar Evaporation Ponds and Conveyance


                 Volume   Conveyance    Costs,71,000 gal, waste
Waste Volume    Conveyed     Cost      Conveyance  Ponds Tucson

100,000  gpd       —         —          —         $ 0.455
500,000  gpd     10,000   $ 310/day     $ 0.62
      1  mgd     10,000     310/day       0.31         0.378
      5  mgd    100,000    3000/day       0.60
     10  mgd    100,000    3000/day       0.30         0.354


Koenig's data assumed concentration by distillation and the
degree of  concentration was optimized.  There would be no
such economies in  solar evaporation ponds and the maximum
concentration can  be assumed.  Assuming that the pond cost
is  the capital cost and conveyance cost is the operating cost,
costs are  shown in Table 21.
                          41

-------
            Table 21.  Solar Evaporation Costs


                Cost per 1,000 gal. Waste WaterDisposed
Daily Volume   Operating CostAnnualized Capital Cos't

  100,000         $ 0.300                 $ 0.455
  500,000           0.300                   0.417
    1 mgd           0.300                   0.378
    5 mgd           0.300                   0.366
   10 mgd           0.300                   0.354
Incineration

Koenig estimates the cost of incineration at 4.8* per 1,000
gallon of product water in a 100 mgd AWT plant at 95 percent
product water production.  Daily costs here would thus be
$4,560 for the disposal of 5 mgd of waste water, or $0.912
per 1,000 gallons.  The ash produced might be disposed of
in a landfill.  Assuming 1,500 ppm of dissolved solids in
5 mgd, the ash would be about 62,475 Ibs or 31.2 tons per
day in such a plant.  For a 100 mgd AWT plant at a 99.5
percent product water rate the cost of spreading is 0.1*
per 1,000 gallon of product water, $99.50 per day, or about
20* per 1,000 gallon of waste water.  These figures seem
to confirm the conclusion in WP-20-AWTR-19 that such disposal
means cost about the same as ocean disposal.

The limiting factor in the general applicability of incine-
ration would be the availability and cost of fuel.  Koenig's
data seem to be based upon a minimum fuel cost probably only
available at the well for natural gas.  Assuming the avail-
ability of waste heat and/or by-product fuels in industrial
plants, the cost of incineration may be assumed to be the
highest cost for ocean disposal, i.e., as in Koenig's data
for 500,000 gpd at a distance of 1,000 miles.

Regional Applicability

The states in which solar evaporation probably represents a
viable disposal method are:  Arizona, New Mexico, Nevada,
Utah, Colorado and Wyoming on the basis of the evaporation
rates in Table 22 and precipitation rates in the map of
Figure 13.

Deepwell disposal is probably a feasible disposal method in
the following states as indicated on the map on Figure 14.
                         42

-------
                         Table 22.   Mean Monthly Computed Reservoir Evaporation
                                  At Selected Stations,  in Inches Depth
u>
Station
Sacramento. Calif 	
Seattle, Wash. ......
Baker, Oregon 	
Salt Lake City, Utah...
Yuma, Arizona 	
Havre, Montana 	
Bismark, N. Dakota 	
Denver, Colorado 	
North Platte, Nebr. . .
Roswell, N. Mexico 	
Oklahoma City, Okla. . . .
San Antonio, Texas.....
Calves ton, Texas 	
Minneapolis , Minn 	


Vicksburg, Miss 	
Nashville , Tenn.. .......
Columbus, Ohio 	
Macon , Georgia 	
Miami, Florida.-. .......
Columbia, S. C 	 . ...

Albany , N . Y . . . . 	
Eastport, Me 	
Gulf off Texas Coast. . .
Gulf Stream off Cape...
Hat terns , N.C 	
Ocean off Mass 	

Month :
Jan
0.8
0.8
0.5
0.8
3.9
0.5
0.4
1.6
0.8
2.1
1.5
2.2
0.9
0.3
0.6
0.9
1.3
0.9
0.6
1.7
3.0
1.6
1.3
0.6
0.8
4.0
9.0
3.0
Feb
1.4
0,8
0.7
1.0
4.6
0.5
0.5
1.8
1.1
3.2
1.9
3.1
1.3
0.4
0.7
1.1
1.9
1.3
0.8
2.2
3.4
2.4
1.7
0.7
0.7
4.0
9.5
2.5
Mar
2.5
1.4
1.4
2.0
6.5
1.1
1.0
2.5
2.2
4.9
3.1
4.5
1.6
0.9
0.9
1.7
2.9
1.9
1.1
3.1
4.1
3.2
2.2
1.1
0.9
3.5
8.5
2.0
Apr
3.6
2.1
2.5
3.5
8.0
2.5
2.3
3.7
3.7
6.8
4.7
5.6
2.6
1.7
1.3
3.1
4.2
3.3
2.3
4". 3
4.9
4.5
3.5
2.0
1.1
3.5
7.0
1.5
May
5.0
2.7
3.4
5.1
9.8
4.5
4.0
5.0
5.0.
8.3
5.5
6.5
4.1
3.2
2.1
4.4
5.0
4.1
3.5
5.1
5.0
5.4
4.1
3.2
1.4
4.0
5.5
1.0
June
7.1
3.4
4.4
7.9
11.5
6.1
5.3
7.4
6.5
9.8
7.8
8.4
5.6
4.4
3.2
6.1
5.7
5.1
4.6
6.2
4.8
6.3
5.0
4.3
1.7
4.5
3.5
1.5
July
8.9
3.9
6.9
10.6
13.4
8.2
7.3
8.8
8.6
9.4
10.2
9.4
6.2
6.0
5.0
8.0
5.8
5.8
5.6
6.3
5.3
6,6
5.6
5.2
2.0
5.0
3.5
1.5
Aug
8.6
3.4
7.3
L0.4
L2.9
8.3
7.7
8.4
8.4
8.3
L0.7
9.4
6.1
5.8
5.4
7.8
5.5
5.4
5.1
5.8
5.1
6.0
4.9
4.7
2.1
5.5
3.5
2.0
Sept
7.1
2.6
4.9
7.3
10.7
5.6
5.8
6.7
6.9
6.9
8.8
7.6
5.7
4.6
4.7
6.0
5.2
4.9
4.1
5.2
4.3
5.5
4.1
3.4
2.0
6.5
5.5
2.5
Oct
4.8
1.6
2.9
3.9
8.0
3.3
3.3
4.6
4.6
5.5
6.3
5.8
4.6
3.0
3.2
4.5
4.4
3.7
3.0
4.2
4.1
4.4
3.2
2.4
1.6
6.5
9.0
3.0
NOV
2.6
1.1
1.5
2.0
6.1
1.5
1.3
3.0
2.6
3.5
3.5
3.7
2.7
1.3
1.6
2.5
2.9
2.1
1.6
2.8
4.3
3.0
2.4
1.4
1.1
6.0
9.5
3.5
Dec
1.2
0.7
0.6
1.0
4.5
0.7
0.5
1.9
1.1
2.5
2.0
2.4
1.3
0.4
0.6
1.0
1.6
1.1
0.6
1.8
2.7
1.9
1.5
0.8
0.7
5.0
10.0
4.0
Annual
54
24
37
55
100
43
39
55
51
71
66
69
43
32
29
47
46
39
33
49
51
51
39
30
16
58
84
28

-------
                                                                                 75 to 100
                                                                                  and over
FIGURE 13.   AVERAGE AilHUAL PRECIPITATION FOR THE UNITED STATES

-------
FIGURE 14,  AREAS OF POTENTIAL INJECTION SITES (SEDIMENTARY BASINS)

-------
        Table 23.   Gross Water Uses and Water Intakes of Brackish and Fresh Tidewaters  by State
                                                                 Billion Gallons Pec Year
State

New England
   Maine
   New Hampshire
   Vermont
   Massachusetts
   Rhode Island
   Connecticut

Middle Atlantic
   New York
   New Jersey
   Pennsylvania

East North Central
   Ohio
   Indiana
   Illinois
   Michigan
   Wisconsin

West North Central
   Minnesota
   Iowa
   Missouri
   ilorth Dakota
   South Dakota
   Nebraska
   Kansas

South Atlantic
   Delaware
   Maryland
   D. C.
   Virginia
   West Virginia
   North Carolina
   South Carolina
   Georgia
   Florida

East South Central
   Kentucky
   Tennessee
   Alabama
   Mississippi

West South Central
   Arkansas
   Louisiana
   Oklahoma
   Texas

Mountain
   Montana
   Idaho
   Wyoming
   Colorado
   New Mexico
   Arizona
   Utah
   Nevada

Pacific
   Washington
   Oregon
   California
   Alaska
   Hawa i i
   Total
(1)  Disposal Means:
     (1)
                                    Establishments
                 65
                 57
                 22
                275
                 73
                214
                540
                418
                678
                717
                347
                626
                475
                375
                191
                137
                185
                  7
                 12
                 63
                 86
                 53
                135
                  4
                156
                 77
                302
                188
                229
                142
                140
                210
                184
                 95
                107
                182
                 62
                389
                 24
                 63
                 11
                 63
                 12
                 30
                 34
                 11
                167
                129
                585
                 12
                 28
              9,402
Gross
Water Use
317.3
108.1
17.7
264.3
30.1
239.1
995.9
797.9
2559.9
2157.1
1621.6
1666.6
1533.0
523.0
231.2
132.1
339.6
17.5
9.1
72.7
348.6
259.1
581.0
0.2
741.4
824.1
487.1
476.7
721.9
948.7
435.7
843.9
97-1.3
376.0
456.8
2279.1
309.5
6903.3
109.1
162.3
40.5
160.5
5.3
111.3
181.4
29.4
1105.7
368.0
1506.4
116.0
156.7
,700.6
Brackish
Intake
7.4
0.3
Z
44.3
2.5
34.6
18.0
195.2
8.5
17.2
0.5
10.3
147.0
3.7
0.7
0.1
4.1
-
Z
-
1.7
136.5
280.2
-
63.0
3.6
0.8
12.2
41.7
81.4
0.1
Z
82.6
5.1
0.8
244.0
0.6
1368.8
0.3
0.4
-
0.2
-
1.9
7.6
-
185.0
12.5
132.1
1.9
19.3
3,013.0
Fresh
Tidewater Intake
1.3
-
-
0.2
-
85.0
7.0 '
67.3
123.5
— • .
-
-
-
~
-_
, -
-
r ~
-
-
-
27.6
0.2
-
92.2
-
-
0.9
-
0.1
—
-
-
-
_
5.4
-
0.5
_
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
33.2
15.4
11.7
-
0.7
444.1
x Deepwell
0 Solar Evaporation   - Ocean/Incineration
                                        46

-------
          North Dakota
          South Dakota
          Nebraska
          Kansas
          Oklahoma
          Texas
          West Virginia
          Michigan
                                    Louisiana
                                    Mississippi
                                    Florida
                                    Kentucky
                                    Illinois
                                    Indiana
                                    Ohio
                                    Tennessee
In the other states, the most likely disposal means are to
the ocean in coastal areas and by incineration/landfill in
the inland states or inland portions of coastal states.
The costs of such methods will be taken as equal to ocean
disposal at 100 miles distance.

Gross water uses and water intakes of brackish and fresh
tidewater by state are shown in Table 23.  These data are
summarized below in Table 24 for the states previously
listed in which the three groups of disposal means are
applicable.
Table 24.  Summary of Water Uses and Residual Disposal Means
                              Billion Gallons Per Year
Disposal                  Gross    Brackish
Means       Establish.  Water Use   Intake

Deep Well
Solar
  Evaporation
Ocean/Incinera-
  tion
3,558
n 166
ra—
5,678
19,522.4
528.4
15,649.8
1,876.7
9.7
1,126.6
                                              Fresh Tidewater
                                                 Intake	

                                                  6.0
                                                438.1
The costs for residual waste water disposal will be assumed
herein as summarized in Table  25.
                          47

-------
      Table 25.  Summary of Residual Disposal Costs
                           Costs per 1,000 gal, disposed^
Disposal Means

Ocean Disposal
    @ 100 miles:
    500,000 gpd
  1,000,000 gpd
  5,000,000 gpd
 10,000,000 gpd
  Incineration/
  Landfill
Deepwell Disposal
    100,000 gpd
    500,000 gpd
  1,000,000 gpd
Solar Evaporation
    100,000 gpd
    500,000 gpd
  1,000,000 gpd
  •5,000,000 gpd
 10,000,000 gpd
Operating
  Costs
 $ 1.00
 $ 0.75
 $ 0.44
 $ 0.29

 $ 1.52

 $ 0.46
 $ 0.25
 $ 0.20

 $ 0.30
 $ 0.30
 $ 0.30
 $ 0.30
 $ 0.30
Annualized Cap.
    Cost           Total
   $ 0.84          $ 1.84
   $ 0.56          $ 1.31
   $ 0.28          $ 0.72
   $ 0.24          $ 0.53

   $ 1.24          $ 2.76

   $ 0.64          $ 1.10
   $ 0.15          $ 0.40
   $ 0.085         $ 0.29

   $ 0.46          $ 0.76
   $ 0.42          $ 0.72
   $ 0.38          $ 0.67
   $ 0.37          $ 0.67
   $ 0.35          $ 0.65
Total annualized disposal costs, as above, are shown in
Figure 15.
                          48

-------
o
o
o
C
C
H
m
•P
o
EH
   3.00
    2.50
    2.00
-p
CO
o
u

H
(0
05
0


.»   1.50

Q

t)
Q)
N
•H
H
(C
    1.00
      50
                               Incineration
                                         Ocean  Disposal  @  100  miles
           \
Solar Evaporation
              »
                       Deepwell Disposal
         01234


         FIGURE  15,   TOTAL ANNUALIZED RESIDUAL DISPOSAL COSTS
                                       49

-------
                        SECTION IX

       COSTS OF INDUSTRY SYSTEMS FOR ZERO DISCHARGE

On the basis of the data developed, the costs of water
pollution abatement are estimated for each of the major
water-using industries at five levels as follow:

1.  Once-through systems
    In such a system, water is used once-through for all
uses and process water is treated to the extent required
to meet existing water quality standards in a terminal
treatment facility.

2.  Existing Practice
    Water use is as indicated by the 1968 Census of
Manufacturers data and treatment is generally of process
water in terminal treatment facilities prior  to discharge.

3.  Meeting Stream Quality Standards
    Water use is as indicated by the 1968 Census of Manu-
facturers and treatment is of process water in terminal
treatment facilities to meet existing water quality
standards.

4.  Implement Minimum Discharge  (Best Available Treatment)
    Water use is with maximum re-use and treatment is of
process water in terminal treatment facilities to meet
existing water quality standards.

5.  Implement Zero Discharge
    Water use is with maximum re-use, concentration of
residual streams from all uses, and non-discharge disposal
of brines.

The methods by which these costs were calculated are illustrated
below for the Primary Metal Industries,  (S.I.C. No. 33).
Costs for the other industry groups at the 2-digit S.I-C.
level were calculated in an analogous manner.

Projections of physical output were used as data were avail-
able; otherwise projections were based on values of shipments.
Numbers of establishments in each industry group were used
as shown in Table 26.

Primary Metal Industries Calculations

The cost of waste water treatment facilities installed  in
1968 was estimated at $1,324.3 million with $1,473.8 million
needed to meet current needs.  The estimated additional
investment needed to meet growth needs through 1972 was
                           51

-------
  Table 26.  Numbers of Large Water-using Establishments
S.I.C.  No.
    No. of
Establishments
  Total                                              9402
    20  Food and kindred products                    2345
    21  Tobacco manufactures                           24
    22  Textile mill products                         684
    24  Lumber and wood products, except furniture    188
    25  Furniture and fixtures                         55
    26  Paper and allied products                     619
    28  Chemicals and allied products                1125
    29  Petroleum refining and related industries     260
    30  Rubber and miscellaneous plastics products    301
    31  Leather and leather products                   92
    32  Stone, clay, glass and concrete products      586
    33  Primary metal industries                      841
    34  Fabricated metal products,  except machinery
        and transportation equipment                  569
    35  Machinery, except electrical                  471
    36  Electrical and electronic machinery,
        equipment, and supplies                        562
    37  Transportation equipment                      392
    38  Measuring, analyzing, and controlling
        instruments; photographic,  medical,  and
        optical goods; watches and  clocks             107
    39  Miscellaneous manufacturing industries         97
$244.8 million.   Bureau of Domestic Commerce estimates of
the quantities shipped in these industries through 1980 are
as shown in Table 27.
  Table 27.   Projected Primary Metal Industries Shipments



Aluminum, 10 Ibs
Brass Mill,

Copper Wire
106

Mill
Ferrous Castings
Steel Mill
6
Total, 10
Ibs
p.
, 10° Ibs
, 10 tons
Products, 106 tons

tons


1968
9.98
2756

2214
17.867
131.5

151.857
1972
11.6
2900

2525
17.552
139

159.27
1975
14

6600

19.1
147

169.4
1980
20

8700

22.1
166

192.5
                         52

-------
Capital Costs

Utilizing the 1968 water use data and the above estimates of
costs and industry growth, capital costs are projected on the
following bases:

1.  Meeting water quality standards:  projected proportionately
from 1968-1972 costs and growth:


                      =  $ 33.0 million/million annual tons


2.  Existing practice:  projected on the basis of 1968 costs
per ton:


             = $8.72 million/million annual tons


3.  Minimum Discharge

    Process water discharge =  5% of recirculation rate = 114

    Other discharges = 1% of recirculation rate less boiler
    feed and sanitary plus boiler feed and sanitary discharges:

    = 0.01  (5495-236) + 155 =  208 x 109 gal.

    Costs for 1968:

    Costs of treating discharges to level acceptable for
    discharge/reuse                         $ 1,473.8 million

    Costs for recirculating:
                             9                  c
     (1134 + 3562) =  4696 x 10  gal. = 8.935 x 10° gpm

    Intake system =  8.935 x 106 x $16.25 = $145 million

    Distribution system = 8.935 x 106 x $36.50 = $326 million

    Costs of cooling towers:

    Recirculation rate = 8.935 x 10  gpm

    No. establishments = 841

    Average per plant recirculation rate = 10,624 gpm

    Cooling tower cost = $17/gpm $180,000  ( 13)

    Cooling tower cost = $152  million
                          53

-------
Total 1968 costs for the industry = $2,096.8 million

Projected proportionately on basis of costs of implementing
existing legislation.

    for 1972:  1718.6  x $2096.8 = $2445.0 million
               1473.8
4.  Implement zero discharge:

    Costs for 1968:

    Blowdown = 114 + 208 = 322 x 109 gal. = 882.2 x 106 gal/day

    No. of establishments - 841

    Average blowdown - 1.049 mgd

    Distillation cost = $1.60/gpd ($1.679 million)  (3)

    Disillation cost total = $1412 million
                                      9
    Brine production = 0.10 x 322 x 10  gal./year =
                                          88.2 x 106 gal./day

    No. of establishments = 841

    Average brine = 104,900 gpd

The quantities of brine to be disposed of by the various
residual disposal means are calculated below from Table 28,
which was constructed from the Census of Manufactures data
for S.I.C. No. 33 and the regional applicability of each
method as shown in Table 23.  The calculation of (D)  assumes
equal volumes in each state.

       Ocean                      437.1 + 2D
       Incineration              3068.6 + 4D
       Deepwell                  3748.6 + 5D
       Sol. Evap.                  69.6 + 3D
       Total                     7323.9 + 14D

       14D =  (2285 + 5495) - 7323.9 = 456.1; D=32.6

       Ocean                      502.3 = 6.46%
       Incineration              3199.0 = 41.12%
       Deepwell                  3911.6 = 50.27%
       Sol. Evap.                 167.4 = 2.15%
                          54

-------
                             Table  28.   Brine Disposal Means - S.I.C.  33
                                          Gross Water Used,   109 gallon	
                                         Incineration    peepwell      Solar Evaporation
Maine                         -
New Hampshire                 D
Vermont                       -
Massachusetts                4.5
Rhode Island                 7.4
Connecticut                   -              33.9
New York                      -             331.1
New Jersey                  36.7               -i
Pennsylvania                  -            1508.2
Ohio                          -                -           1152.7
Indiana                       -                -           1118.8
Illinois                      -                -            531.3
Michigan                      -                -            626.4
Wisconsin                     -              13.8
Minnesota                     -              19.1
Iowa                          -              25.7
Missouri                      -              31.7
North Dakota                                                -r
South Dakota                  -
Nebraska                                                    D
Kansas                                                      D
Delaware                      D
Maryland                      -             372.6
D.C.                          -
Virginia                    11.2
West Virginia                 -             221.4
North Carolina               -               4.5
South Carolina               -                D             -
Georgia                       -              28.2
Florida                       -                -             D
Kentucky                      -                -             72,8
Tennessee                     -                -             33.4  ,.
Alabama                       -             335.5
Mississippi                   -                -             D
Arkansas                      -                D             -
Louisiana                     -                -             D    .
Oklahoma                      -                ~             3•5
Texas                      210.7              -           210.7
Montana                       -                D             -
Idaho                         _                D             -
Wyoming                       _                -             -                  -
Colorado                      -                                                 D
N.  Mexico                     -                -                                -
Arizona                       -                ~>                              69-
Utah                          -                                                °
Nevada                        -               ~
Washington                   -            128.1
Oregon                        *             14-8
California                166.6              -                                ~
Alaska                        ~                                                ~
Hawaii                        _               -             -

        (D)   Withheld to avoid disclosing data for individual firms.

-------
Deepwell cost = [0.502 (88.2 x 106 gpd) T 100,0003 x $200,000
                                              = $88.55 million

Solar evaporation cost:

$0.455 x 104.9 x 365  x 841 x 0.0215 x 8.5136 = $2.68 million

Incineration cost:

$1.24 x 104.9 x 841 x 0.4112 x 8.5136 = $139.8 million

Ocean disposal cost:

$0.84 x 104.9 x 365 x 841 x 0.0646 x 8.5136 = $14.9 million

Added cost for zero discharge = $1657.9 million

1968 costs for best available technology + zero discharge =
$3754.7 million

Projected proportionately as for minimum discharge

Operating Costs

Operating costs for- the industry in 1968 were estimated to be
$137.8 million per year.   Since the treatment facilities are
of the same type, the ratio of $137-8/$1324.3, or $0.104 per
year per dollar of capital investment can. be used to estimate
and project operating costs for 1968 practice and of meeting
water quality standards.

The operating costs for implementation of minimum discharge
are the costs of recirculation of the treated effluents.
Referring to the previously given steel industry water use
costs  (p. 32 ) 'in 20 plants for 1509.6 mgd:

Manufacturing Costs:

   Chemicals                         2251
   Labor                             7280
   Maintenance and Power              7984
   Payroll and Plant Overhead        5470
   Laboratory                        0.20 x 7280
   Property taxes and insurance       606
   Royalties and patents              0.01 x total cost
                         56

-------
General Expense:

   Administration                        0.06 x mfg cost
   Research                              0.10 x mfg cost
   Interest on working capital           0.08 x total cost

Total Cost = General Expense + Mfg Cost  = T

Total Cost then is:

  ($25047 + 0.01 T) + 0.16  ($25047 + 0.01T) + 0.08T

   T = $29055 + 0.0916T = $31985/1509.6  mgd = $21.19 per mgd

The additional operating costs then are  for recirculating
1134 + 3562, or 4696 x 109 gallon per year, i.e., $21.19
x 4696 x 10-3, or $99.5 million per year.  These costs may be
projected proportionately with the capital costs for imple-
menting minimum discharge.

The operating costs for zero discharge in 1968 are:

Distillation @ 1.049 mgd = $0.80 per 1,000 gallon (3)

Distillation cost total =  (322 x 109) x  ($0.80 x 10~3^  =
                                           $ 257.6 million

Deepwell cost = 0.5027 x 32.2 x 109 x $0.46 x 10~3 = $7.4 million
                                           9              7
Solar Evaporation Cost = 0.0215 x 32.2 x 10  x $0-30 x 10~J =
                                           $0.2 million

Incineration Cost = 0.4112 x 32,2 x 109  x $1.52 x 10~3 = $20.1 mil

Ocean Disposal Cost = 0-0646 x 32.2 x 109 x $1.00 x 10~3 = $2.1 mil

Total added operating costs then are $287.4 million in 1968
and may be projected in proportion to capital costs.

If all water were used on a once-through"basis and treated to
meet existing legislative requirements,  the costs would pre-
sumably be less by the cost of existing  recirculation and more
by the proportionate residual costs of meeting such requirements
by current treatment methods.
                                                        g
For the primary metals industries, 1185-1134, or 51 x 10
gallons per year of process water were recirculated in 1968,
i.e., 2.190 x 106 gpm.  The capital costs of such recirculation,
as shown previously would be:
                           57

-------
   Intake system:  2.190 x 10^ x $16.25 = $35.6 million
   Distribution:   2.190 x 106 x $36.50 = $79.9 million
   Cooling towers: 2.190 x 106 x $17.00 = $37.2 million

                              Total       $152.7 million

The residual capital cost in 1968 would have been $1473.8 -
$152.7 = $1321.1 million for the treatment of 1431 x 10 9gallons
of effluent water.  The cost of treating the process water flow
of 2285 x 10  gallons would have been:

  2285 °*6  x $1321.1 million = $1749.1 million
  1431

The operating costs, on the basis of the previously shown ratio
of $0.104 per year per dollar of capital investment, would be
estimated at:

  $1749.1 million x $0.104/$ = $181.9 million

These costs were projected proportionately by year as with the
costs of meeting water quality standards.

The costs then for the primary metals industries as calculated
above are summarized in Table 29.

Residual Waste Loads
Net waste loads under existing practice are estimated as shown
in Table 30 through 1977.

The dissolved solids listed in Table 30 are from coke plant wastes
in 1968, projected by estimated steel production.  The apparent
anomally in acid wastes loads is due to the lag in treatment
installation through 1972, followed by treatment of increasing
quantitites due to rising production later.

Net waste loads discharged to meet stream quality standards are
estimated in Table 31, assuming the indicated concentration limits,
and under minimum discharge requirements in Table 32 with treat-
ment of recirculation blowdowns.

Most water quality standards specify a maximum monthly average of
500 mg/1 for dissolved solids and this is assumed as the average
concentration in fresh water.  The Census data specifies brackish
water as containing more than 1,000 mg/1 dissolved solids, but
a more usual definition is about 5,000 mg/1.  Assuming brackish
water intake proportionately as in 1968, the dissolved solids con-
centrated in zero discharge residuals from intake water would be
as shown in Table 33.
                               58

-------
                 Table 29.   Summary of Costs - Primary Metal Industries S.I.C.  33
Ul
                                          Once-   Existing  Implement     Best      Implement
                                         Through  Practice   Existing   Available     Zero
                                        Water Use  (1968)   Legislation   Technology  Discharge
Water Volumes (109 gal.)
Process Uses
Other Uses
Process Discharges
Other Discharges
Treated Discharges
Capital Costs, $106
1968
1972
1975
1980
Operating Costs, $10
1968
1972
1975
1980
2285
5495
2285
5495
2285

1749.1
2039.6
2436.4
3341.1

181.9
212.2
253.4
347.5
2285
5495
1134
3562
1431

1324.3
1388.9
1477.2
1678.6

137.8
144.5
153.7
174.7
2285
5495
1134
3562
1431

1473.8
1718.6
2052.9
2815.2

153.3
178.8
213.6
292.9
2285
5495
114
208
114

2096.8
2445.0
2920.7
4005.2

252.8
294.8
352.1
482.9
2285
5495
0
0
0

3754.7
4378.2
5230.0
7172.0

540.2
629.9
752.5
1031.9

-------
         Table 30.  Existing Practice Waste Loads

                           Loads, 10  pounds per year
                          1968           1972        1977

Suspended Solids          1187           1260        1317
Lubricating Oils          236.1          239.6       233.2
Acids and Salts            614           484.6       560.2
Soluble Metals            6.84           7.47        7.42
Emulsified Oils           23.8           28.1        2.75
Organics (91.5% removal)   2.12           2.30        2.75
Fluorides                 4.37           4.95        5.80
Dissolved Solids          277.7          293.5       326.5
          Table 31.  Stream Standards Waste Loads

                            Loads, 10  pounds per year
                          1968    1972      1975    1980
Suspended Solids (lOppm)   94.5    99.9     105.7    119.3
Oils (5ppm)               47.2    49.9      52.8     59.6
Dissolved Solids         277.7   293.5     310.4    350.6
Iron (7ppm)               66.2    70.0      74.0     83.6
Organics (99% removal)     0.24    0.25      0.27     0.30
         Table 32.  Minimum Discharge Waste Loads

                            Loads, 10  pounds per year
                          1S>68    1972      I9T5    1980

Suspended Solids          9.45    9.99      10.75   11.93
Oils                      4.72    4.99       5.28    5.96
Dissolved Solids        277.7   293.5      310.4   350.6
Iron                      6.62    7.00       7.40    8.36
Organics                  0.24    0.25       0.27    0.30
  Table 33.  Intake Dissolved Solids Discharged in Brine


Year                     Dissolved Solids, 10  pounds per year

1968                                   6,957
1972                                   7,353
1975                                   7,777
1980                                   8,782
                          60

-------
The residual loads then  to underground  aquifers  (deepwell
disposal), the oceans  (ocean  disposal),  the  air  (incineration),
and land  (solar evaporation)  are  projected through  1980 in
Table 34.  The disposition of inorganics from  incineration
is assumed to be to  the  land.

Electric  Power Industry  Calculations

The nature of the electric power  industry is such that the
calculations are somewhat different than for the manu-
facturing industries.  These  calculations are, therefore,
separately detailed  below.  Water uses, and  discharges, and
waste heat loads are tabulated in Table 35 from the data
developed earlier herein.
             Table  34.   Zero Discharge  Residuals
                    (Million Ibs  per  year)
 Substance

 Suspended
  Solids
 Oils
 Dissolved
  Solids
 Iron
 Organics
                    Underground
'68
      72
75
80
4.75  5.01  5.30  5.98
2.37  2.50  2.64  2.97

3636  3843  4064  4589
3.33  3.53  3.73  4.21
0.12  0.13  0.03  0.14
'68
                                   Ocean
'72
'75
                          468   495
                         0.43  0.45
                         0.02  0.02
80
                         0.61  0.65  0.69   0.78
                         0.31  0.33  0-35   0.40
                          524    592
                         0.48   0.54
                         0.03   0.03
                       Air
                                   Land
 Substance

 Suspended
  Solids
 Oils
 Dissolved
  Solids
 Iron
 Organics
68   '72   '75
                   80
1.94  2.05  2.17  2.45
0.09  0.09  0.10  0.11
'68
4.09
0.10
3131
2.86
0.01
'72
4.33
0.11
3309
3.02
0.01
'75
4.58
0.12
3499
3.19
0.01
'80
5.17
0.14
3952
3.61
0.02
                           61

-------
                      Tablo 35.   Electric Power Industry  Waste  w'atsr  Parameters

                                        Q                             1 O
                      (water volumes,  10  gallons,  hdat discharges, 10   BTU)
1968:
   Cooling Water Use
   Cooling Water Discharge
   Heat Discharge
                                   Once-through
                                       Water
                                       Us •?
 61,412
 61,412
  5,874
                 Existing
                 Practice
                  (1963)
 61,412
 54,385
  5,203
                 Implement
                 Existing
                Legislation
 61,412
    614
 58.7
               Implement
                  Zero
               Discharge
 61,412
   0
   0
1972:
   Cooling Water Use
   Cooling Water Discharge
   Heat Discharge
 83,156
 83,156
  7,405
 83,156
 73,950
  6,625
 83,156
    832
 74.1
 83,156
   0
   0
1975:
   Cooling Water Use
   Cooling Water Discharge
   Heat Discharge
106,347
106,347
  9,404
106,347
 95,356
  8,550
106,347
  1,063
 94.0
106,347
   0
   0
1980:
   Cooling Water Use
   Cooling Water Discharge
   Heat Discharge
145,043
145,043
 12,015
145,043
130,043
 11,066
145,043
  1,450
120.2
145,043
   0
   0
                                      62

-------
         Table 36.  Power Plant Cooling Water Use
      Cooling Water Use 1(T gal.  No. of Plants   mgd per plant
1968
1972
1975
1980
 61,412
 83,156
106,347
145,043
  984
1,025
1,073
1,140
171
222
272
349
With blowdown at 1% of the recirculation rate, the discharge
per plant would be as follows, and multiple-effect evapo-
ration units at the indicated unit costs would result in
total industry costs as indicated in Table 37.
1968
1972
1975
1980
        Table 37.  Power Plant Distillation Costs
                           i
Year  Blowdown, mgd per pldnt
 1.71
 2.22
 2.72
 3.49
                                Unit Cost Total Cost
                  No. of plants  $/gpd    $ Billion
984
1,025
1,073
1,140
1.30
1.25
1.20
1.10
2.187
2.844
3.502
4.376
Brine production then would be as shown in Table 38, at 10%
of the distillation throughout:

         Table 38.  Power Plant Brine Production
       Brine, gpd
Year    per plant

1968    171,000
1971    222,000
1975    272,000
1980    349,000
        No. of Plants

             984
           1,025
           1,073
           1,140
       Total Brine
     per year, 109 gal,

         61.412
         83.156
        106.347
        145.043
The percentages of  brine  disposal means were assumed to be
the same as  the distribution of population in the states in
which each of  the several methods were previously shown to
be applicable  and as  detailed  in Table 39.
                           63

-------
The 1968 annualized capital costs for brine disposal then
are calculated as follows:

Deepwell = $0.64 - $(0.64-0.15) x 71    61,412,000 x 0.3677
                   400

x 8.5136 = $106.3 million

Solar Evaporation = $0.45 x 61,412,000 x 0.0299 x 8.5136 =

$7.03 million

Incineration = $1.24 x 61,412,000 x 0.4500 x 8.5136 =

$291.7 million

Ocean Disposal = $0.84 x 61,412,000 x 0.1524 x 8.5136 =

$66.9 million

Total capital costs for brine disposal = $471.9 million

Operating Costs

The operating costs of recirculation in the electric power
industry are estimated at 0.5C per 1,000 gallon (4).  Capital
and operating costs are estimated as above for the year 1968
and projected in proportion to the respective water use
volume in the following table.

The recirculation percentage of existing practice is taken
at 13 percent, i.e., the capital costs of 1968 practice is
13 percent of that for complete recirculation.

Operating costs for zero discharge in 1968 then are:

Distillation @ 1.71 mgd = $0.71 per 1,000 gallon (3)

Distillation cost total = (614.12 x 109) (0.71 x 10~3)  =

$436.0 million

Deepwell = 61,412,000 x 0.3677 x $0.46 - $(0.46-0.25) x 71

$9.55 million

Solar Evaporation = 61,412,000 x 0.0299 x $0.30 = $0.55 million

Incineration = 61,412,000 x 0.4500 x $1.52 = $42.0 million

Ocean Disposal = 61,412,000 x 0.1524 x $1.00 = $9.36 million
                          64

-------
The electric power industry water uses, discharges and costs
are summarized through  1980 in Table  40, projected by year
according to estimated  production.

Residual Waste Loads Under Zero  Discharge

The electric power industry residual  waste  loads are the heat
rejected in cooling water on  a once-through basis, to the
air via evaporative cooling,  and the  dissolved  solids in the
intake water calculated as previously discussed under the
primary metals industries example.

Summaries of Costs and  Residual  Waste Loads

In Tables 41 through  48, costs and  residual waste loads under
zero  discharge in 1980  are summarized for  the manufacturing
industries  studied and  the electric power  industry.
Capital costs are presented'as annualized  costs.
                            65

-------
           Table 39.  Percentage Distribution of Disposal Means - Electric Power Industry



State                     Ocean      Inoingration      Deepwell      Solar Evaporation

Maine                      0.24          0.24
New Hampshire                            0.35
Vermont                                  0.21
Massachusetts              1.37          1.37
Rhode Island               0.23          0.23
Connecticut                0.74          0.74
New York                                 9.05
New Jersey                1.77          1.77
Pennsylvania                             5.87
Ohio                                                    5.30
Indiana                                                 2.53
Illinois                                                5.50
Michigan                                                4.37
Wisconsin                                2.11
Minnesota                                1.82
Iowa                                     1.39'
Missouri                                 2.31
North Dakota                                            0.31
South Dakota                                            0.33
Nebraska                                                0.72
Kansas                                                  1.15
Delaware                   0.13          0.13
Maryland                                 1.88
D. C.                                    0.40
Virginia                   1.15          1.15
West Virginia                            0.90
North Carolina             1.23          1.28
South Carolina             0.67          0.67
Georgia                    1.14          1.14
Florida                                                 3.08
Kentucky                                                1.61
Tennessee                                               1.99
Alabama                                  1.78
Mississippi                                             1.17
Arkansas                                 0.99
Louisiana                                               1.86
Oklahoma                                                1.26
Texas                                                   5.49
Montana                                  0.35
Idaho                                    0.35
Wyoming                                                                     0.16
Colorado                                                                    1.02
New Mexico                                                                  0.50
Arizona                                                                     0.83
Utah                                                                        0.22
Nevada                                                                      0.22
Washington                 0.82          0.82
Oregon                     0.50          0.50
California                 4.83          4.83
Alaska                     0.07          0.07
Hawaii                     0.20          0.20

TOTALS                    15.24         45.00          36.77                2.99
                                      66

-------
                    Table 40.  Electric Power Industry cost and Discharge Summary
                                       Once-
                                       Through
                                     Water Use
              Existing
              Practice
                (1963)
             Implementing
                Existing
              Legislation
                  Implementing
                      Zero
                   Discharge
Water Volumes  (10* gal.):

   Cooling Water Use

        1963
        1972
        1975
        1980
 61,412
 83,156
106,347
145,043
 61,412
 83,156
106,347
145,043
 61,412
 83,156
106,347
145,043
 61,412
 83,156
106,347
145,043
Water Discharged

         1968
         1972
         1975
         1980
 61,412
 83,156
106,347
145,043
 54,385
 73,950
 95,356
130,043
    614
    832
  1,063
  1,450
 Capital Costs,  $10e

         1968
         1972
         1975
         1980
   0
   0
   0
   0
    158
    214
    274
    373
  1,215
  1,645
  2,104
  2,870
  3,874
  5,129
  6,423
  8,361
 Operating Costs, $10

         1968
         1972
         1975
         1980
   0
   0
   0
   0
   39.9
   54.0
   69.1
   94.2
    307
    416
    532
    725
    497
    646
    791
  1,015
                                          67

-------
Table 41.   Summary of  Costs'and Residual Waste Loads



                   PRIMARY METALS

Once-through
Water Use
Existing
Practice
U&68)
Implement
Existing
Legislation
Implement Implement
Minimum Zaro
Discharge Discharge
Water Volume (109 gal. per year) : (1968):
Process Uses
Other Uses
Process Discharge
Other Discharge
Treated Discharge
Annualized Capital Costs
1968
1972
1975
1980
Annual Operating Costs ($
1963
1972
1975
1980
2285
5495
2285
5495
2285
(S millibn, 1968,
205.4
239.6
20G.2
392.4
Efillion, 1968) :
131.9
212.1
253.4
347.5
Residual Waste Loads Under Zero Discharge
Underground
Ocean
Air
Land




2285
5495
1134
3562
1431
10 year @ 8%) :
115.6
163.1
173.5
197.2

137.8
144.5
153.7
174.7
(106 #/yr, 1980) :
Organics and Oils
3.1
0.4
2.6
0.2
2285
5495
1134
3562
1431

173.1
201.9
241.1
330.7

153.3
178.8
213.6
292.9

Suspended Solids
10.2
1.3
-
8.8
2235
5495
114
208
114

246.3
287.2
343.1
470.4

252.8
194.8
352.1
482.9

Dissolved Solids
4589
592
-
3952
2285
5495
0
0
0

441.0
514.3
614.3
842.4

540.2
629.9
752.5
1032





                  68

-------
                        Table 42.  Summary of Costs and Residual Waste  Loads




                                      PAPER AND ALLIED PRODUCTS
Process Uses



Other Uses



Process Discharge



Other Discharge



Treated Discharge





Annual Capital Cos



1963



1972



1375



1980
 1968



 1972




 1975



 1980
 Underground




 Ocean



 Air



 Land
Existing Imolement
Once-through Practice Existing
Water Use (1968) Laaislafcion
sar) : (1968) ;
5166
1356
5166
1356
5166
ion, 1968, 10 yr @ ;
42.5
47.3
50.9
57.0
llion, 1968):
49.2
54.8
59.0
66.0
iero Discharge (10
B.O.D.
3.5
3.3
10.0
0.3

5166
1356
1363
715
915
B%):
23.9
32.2
34.7
38.8

33.3
37.3
40.1
44.9
l/yr, 1980):
Suspended
3.9
3.6
11.1
0.3

5166
1356
1363
1356
1363

37.8
42.1
45.3
50.7

43.8
48.7
52.5
58.7

Solids




Implement
Minimum
Discharge

5166
1356
517
206
517

82.0
91.3
98.3
110.0

182.3
203.0
218.6
244.5

Dissolved Soliu=
4231
3992
-
12488
Implement
Zero
Discharge

5166
1356
0
0
0

431.9
431.0
518.0
579.2

736.3
820.0
883.1
987.4






                                                69

-------
                         Table 43.  Suaraary o;.' Costs and RaJiduiil Waste Loads
                                    CHEMICALS A::D ALLIED PRODUCTS
Once-through
Water r/se
:ar) : (196S);
1270
8146
1270
8146
1270
dllion, 1968,
I
119.1
138.0
156.8
187.1
.lion, 1968):
201.8
236.7
272.3
325.1
tro Discharge


Existing
Pr.-vjti'ce
(1968)

127.0
8146
693
3-181
674
10 yr, .3 8%) :
50.8
55.6
61.6
73.6

76.9
83.3
92.7
110.7
Implement
Existing
Legislation

1270
8146
693
3481
693

92.3
106.9
121.5
144.9

156.6
183.7
211.3
252.3
Iaiple;nent
Xiiiinare
Discharge

1270
8145
63. 5
274.0
63.5

160.6
186.1
211.4
252.3

255.2
299.4
344.3
411.2
Inplv.e
Zero
Dischf.r
'
1270
8146
0
0
0

361.9
419.3
476.5
568.6

559.8
648.6
737.1
879.6
(105 S/yr.- 1930) :
Organics
5.6
2.3
Suspended Solids
34.6
17.0
Dissolved Soli
41,927
20,591
as


Process Uses
Other Uses
Process Discharge
Other Discharge
Treated Discharge

Annualized Capital
1968
1972
1S75
1980

Annual Operating C
1968
1972
1975
1980
Underground
Ocean
Mr                                          2.3
Land                                         0.1             14.8
                                                                                 18,006
                                           70

-------
                          Table 44.  Summary of Costs and Residual Waste Loads
                                     PETROLEUM AND COAL PRODUCTS
Once-through
Water Use

-------
                         Table 45.  Summary o? Coits and Residual Waste Loads



                                      FOOD AHQ. "INDRED PRODUCTS
Once-through
Water Use
•ear) : (19<>8)
428
918
423
928
428
;illion, 1968,
110.6
124.4
136.3
183.2
lion, 1968):
153.5
172.6
189.0
254.1
ro Discharge


Existing
Practice
(1968)
:
428
918
270
433
185
10 yr 9 81):
61.4
65.4
68.8
82.4

85.4
90.8
95.5
114.4
Implement
Existing
Legislation
428
918
270
483
270

87.3
98.2
107.5
144.5

121.1
136.2
149.1
200.5
Implement
Minimum
Discharge
428
918
21; 4
95.0
21.4

97.9
110.1
120.5
162.1

134.3
151.0
165.4
222.4
Implement
2ero
Discharge
428
918
0
0
0

133.4
206.1
225.8
303.5

250.4
281.5
308.4
414.7
(106 5/yr, 1930) :
B.O.D.
13.3
10.8
Suspende.1 Solids
21.1
16.6
Dissolved Solids
798
626


Water Volumes  (10  gal. per year):



Process Uses




Other Uses



Process Discharge



Other Discharge



Treated Discharge






Annualized Capital Costs




1968




1972



•1975




1980






Annual Operating Costs ($



1968



1972



1975



1980
Underground



Ocean



Air                                         14.2



Land                                         1.2             23.4
                                                                                    888
                                          72

-------
                        Table  46.   Summary of  Costs  and Residual Waste Loads

                                             TEXTILE  MILLS
                              Once-through
                               Water Use
Existing
Practice
 (1968)
 Implement
  Existing
Legislation
Water Volumes  (10  gal. per  year):   (1968):

Process Uses                       97

Other Uses                        230

Process Discharge                  97

Other Discharge                  230

Treated Discharge                  97


Annualized  Capital Costs *(?  million,  1968,  10 yr @ 8%):

1968                             26.8             16.3

1972                             27.4             16.7

1975                             27.7             15.9

1980                             28.5             17.4


Annual Operating Costs (S million, 1968):

 1968                             64.0

 1972                             65.4

 1975                             66.3

 1980                             68.2


 Residual  Waste Loads Under Zero Discharge (10  5/yr, 1980):

                                            B.O.3.     Suspended Solids

 Underground

 Ocean

 Air                                          125             38

 Land
Implement   Implement
 Minimum       Zero
Discharge   Discharge
97
230
95
41
54
97
230
95
41
95
97
230
9.7
21.9
9.7
97
230
0
0
0
19.4
21.9
23.5
26.8
22.6
25.6
27.4
31.2
33.4
37.7
40.3
46.0
39.0
39.8
40.4
41.5
46.4
52.5
56.1
64.0
53.3
60.3
64.4
73.5
67.6
76.5
81.7
93.2
                            Dissolved Scl ?-•?.?
                                 664
                                           73

-------
                        Table 47.   Summary  of CO3tj and Residual Waste Loads



                             TOTALS OF MANUFACTURING  INDUSTRIES STUDIED

Once-through
Water Use
Existing Implement
Frfictice Existing
(1553) Legislation
Imolement Implement
Minimum Zero
Discharcre Discharge
Water Volumes (10 gal. per year) : (1958) :
Process Uses
Other Uses
Process Discharge
Other Discharge
Treated Discharge
Annualized Capital Costs
1968
1972
1975
1980
Annual Operating Costs (S
1968
1972
1975
1980
9592
23089
9592
23089
9592
(5 million, 1968
536.2
611.4
69.1.7
888. S
million, 1968) :
711.7
808.6
910.9
1139
Residual Waste Loads Under Zero Discharge
Underground
Ocean


9592
23039
3635
9420
4177
, 10 yr 8 8%) :
348.5
371.7
336.5
454.4

432.9
461.6
492.3
562.8
(106 f/yr. 1980) :
Organics Suspended
43.5 69.8
28.4 38.5
9592
23089
3635
10061
4770

454.5
519.6
590.-1
754.1

597.1
682.6
770.3
964.6

Solids


9592
23089
743
965
743

673.2
769.8
874.4
1107

983.0
1123
1266
1568

Dissolved Solids
55,556
28,311
9592
23089
0
0
0

1602
1788
2049
2530

2398
2722
3044
3715



Air                                      157.2             49.1



Land                                        2.3             47.3
                                                                               36,809
                                         74

-------
                        Table 48.  Summary of Costs and Residual Waste Loads



                                       ELECTRIC POWER INDUSTRY
Water Volume  (10  gal. per year):



  Water Uses:  1968



               1972



               1975



               1980



  Water Discharge:



               1968



               1972



               1975



               1980





 Annualized Capital Costs  ($



               1968



               1972



               1975



               1980





 Annual Operating Costs ($ million,  1968):



               1968



               1972



               1975



               1980
Once-through
Water Use
61412
83156
106347
145043
61412
83156
106347
145043
Lion, 1968, 10 yr
0
0
0
0
an, 1968) :
0
0
0
0
Discharge (1930)
Heat,
Existing
Practice
(1963)
61412
83156
106347
145043
54385
73950
95356
130043
§ 8%) ;
18.6
25.1
32.2
43.8

39.9
54.0
69.1
94.2
:
1012 BTU/yr
Implement
Existing
Legislation
61412
83156
106347
145043
614
832
1063
1450

142.7
193.2
247.1
337.1

307
416
532
725

Dissolved
Implement
Zero
Discharge
61412
83156
106347
145043
0
0
0
0

455.0
602.4
754.4
982.,!

497
646
791
1015

Solids, 109 #/yr
 Underground



 Ocean



 Air



 Land
12,015
 9.44



 3.91








12.32
                                        75

-------
                          SECTION  X

                     ECONOMIC ANALYSIS

Those industries studied  represent  93.3% of the industrial
water use in the United States, and extrapolation to all
of the manufacturing industries thus represents little
potential error.  Such an extrapolation is made in Table
49 based upon the ratios  of  process or total water uses as
appropriate.

Production-related data by industry category must be used
with caution in analyzing the economic impact of pollution
control.  The proportions of various industries which include
facilities using significant amounts of water can be seen
in the following tabulation. The 1968 values of shipments
for the respective total  industries and those facilities
which take in more than 20 million  gallons of water annually
are compared in Table 50.
Table 50.
Values of Shipments in Large Water-Using Plants

                                             ,6
                                        Total        20x10
S.I.C. No.          Industry            Industry    gpy Plants
    20
   208
    22
    24
    26
 (1)
    28
   281
    29
  2911
    33
   331
Food and Kindred
Beverages
Textile Mills
Lumber and Wood
Paper and Allied
Paper and Board
Chemical and Allied
Industrial Chemicals
Petroleum and Coal
Petroleum Refining
Primary Metals
Blast Furnace Steel
All Manufacturing
 Industries
 78,259
 10,031
 21,969
  5,257
 22,512
  8,708
 44,826
 14,988
 23,240
 21,395
 44,274
 24,733
631,911
 38,685
  5,304
  9,236
  1,377
  9,996
  7,647
 27,635
 11,756
 19,742
 19,420
 34,803
 20,402
278,037
 7T]	S.I.C.  2621,  2631,  2661,  and (2)  3312,  3345,  3316,  and
     3317


 The data of  Table  51 summarizes data on water  uses,  the
 annual  costs of  implementing existing legislation, values
 added and values of shipments  in the large water-using
 facilities,  and  profits  for the year of 1968 for  the manu-
 facturing and electric power industries.  These data provide
 some first-order measures of the economic significance of
                           77

-------
                        Table  49.   SuFi-iarv ,:>: Costs and Residual Waste  Loads




                                    TOTAL MA-'CS-Y.CTUl'.IMG .INDUSTRIES
Once-through
Water lisa
yr) (1958):
10245
2S456
10245
25456
10245
Existing
Practice
(196S)

10245
25456
3972
10304
4353
Implement
Existing
Lfig.islition

10245
25456
3972
10304
4770
Implement
Minif.ura
Discharge
10245
25456
794
1064
794
Implement
Zero
Discharge

10245
25456
0
0
0






Process Uses




Other Uses




Process Discharge



Other Discharge




Treated Discharge






Annualized Capital  Costs  ($  million,  10 yr @ 8J) :



1968                           572.7             372.2




1972                           653.0             397.0



1975                           741.3             -12.J.5




1330                           948.9             485.3






Annual Operating Costs  (S million,  1963):




1963                           7G0.1



1972                           863.6




1975                           972.8



1980                            1216






Residual Waste Loads Under Zero Dii»charc;<»  C10tJ i-/yr, 1980):




                                            Orga.iics    Suspended Solids



Underground                                   46.5            74.5




Ocean                                         30.3            41.1



Air                                          167.9            52.4




Land                                           2.5            50.5
485.4
554.9
630.:;
805.4
735.1
840.6
954.3
1209
1749
1952
22M
2763
462.3
493.0
325.8
601.1
637.7
729.0
822.7
1030
1073
1226
1382
1712
2619
2972
3324
4057
Dissolvc-d Solid:;



     50567




     30916
                                                                                  40195
                                           78

-------
pollution control costs,  as  shown  in Table  52.


      Table 52.  Pollution Abatement Cost Comparisons


                               Manufacturing  Electric Power
                                 Industries      Industry

Total Annual Costs  as  a percentage of:

Value Added                        0.90            2.84
Value of Shipments                 0.40            2.32
Before-Tax Profits                 4.59            9.39
After-Tax Profits                  7.92           14.98

Total Annual Costs  per:

1,000 gallons  of water used      $0.0315        $0.0073


In Table 53, the total annual  costs of implementing the
various degrees of  discharge reductions are compared with
1968 profits and the effects are estimated under the
assumption that such costs would reduce before-tax profits,
i.e., that there would be no compensating price increases
and that demand would  not change.   Such effects would, of
course, be the maximum in the  short-term; in the long run
these effects  would be less.  Profits in 1968 were made
with the costs of 1968 pollution abatement practices included
in production  costs.   From these data, the cost burdens
of all industry and power, as  reflected in lower after-tax
profits, and the direct public cost, as reflected in reduced
taxes, would have been as shown in Table 54.

   Table 54.   Allocations of Costs of Pollution Control
Pollution Abatement       	Annual Costs,   $ million
    Practice	       Total          Industry      Public

1968 Practice             893.0           524.0        369.0
Existing Legislation      1573            936.0        637.0
Minimum Discharge         2258            1333         925.0
Zero Discharge            5320            3132         2188
                          79

-------
                      Table 51.   Costs, Production, and Katar Use Data - 1963
                                                          Costs to implement Existing  Lagisl.-ttio.n
S.I.C.
No.
-
20
203
22
24
26
28
29
2911
33
331
-
-
S.I.C.
No.
-
20
208
22
24
26
23
29
2911
33
331
-
-
Industry Description
All Industries
Food and Kindred
Beverages
Textile Mills
Lumber and Wood
Paper and Allied
Chemical and Allied
Petroleum & Coal
Petroleum Refining
Primary Metals
Blast Furnaces and
Stoal
Electric Power
All Industry- & Power
Value Added (1) Value
$ Million
125,417
12,067
2,835
3,732
643
4,968
16,131
4,612
4,495
14,798
9,206
15,859
141,276
Water Used
Gross Use Pr
35,701
1,346
211
328
205
6,522
9,416
7,290
7,279
7,780
6,504
61,412
97,113
of Shipments
$ Million
278,037
38,685
5,304
9,236
1,377
9,996
27,635
19,742
19,420
34,803
20,814
19,421
297,458
, 10y ,al,
oc&ss Intake
4,295
291
31
109
37
1,478
733
95
92
1,207
1,049
-
-

(1)
% After Tax
(S.I)8
(2.6)10
(3.9)6
(3. I)10
(5.3)10
(4.7)10
(6.8)8
(10. 6)7
(10. 7)10
(5.3)8
(5.3)9
-
-
Caoital, $106 Annual Ooa--atincr $10
485.4 637-7
87.3 121.1
( 9.3)2 (12. 9)2
19.4 46.4
(4.2)3 (5.5)3
37.8 43.8
92.3 156.6
44.6 75.9
(43. 2)4 (73. 5)4
173.1 153.3
(113. 2)S (10G.2)5
142.7 307.0
628.1 944.7
Profit on Sales
$ .Million $ Million
% Before Tax After Tax Before Tax
(8.8)13 14,180 24,467.
(4.2)11 1,006 1,625
(6.2)11 207 329
(5.0)11 286 462
(8.5)11 73.0 117
(7.5)11 470 750
(10. 9)11 1,879 3,012
(17. O)11 2,093 3,356
(17. I)11 2,078 3,321
(9.8)12 1,845 3,411
(9.8)12 1,103 2,040
3,002 4,789
17,182 29,256
Values in plants taking in more than 20 million gallons annually.
Calculated on ratio of process intakes and total costs in S.I.C. 20.
Calculated on ratio of process intakes and total costs for all industry.
Calculated on ratio of process intakes and total costs in S.I.C. 29.
From "Cost of Clean Water" data.
On basis that profit on sales of 8 largest beverage companies was 1.5
  times the profit of 35 largest food and beverage companies  (Fortune, May 1972)
Other than petroleum refining taken at 5.1%.
(8)   1970 Outlook                          (.11)  Non-Qurable before tax = 1.60 x after
(9)   1972 Outlook                                 tax (.1970 Abstract)
(!0)   1970 Statistical Abstracts           (.12)  Durable before tax = l.SSx after tax
                                                  (If170 Abstract)
                                           C13)  All Mfg. before tax, = 1.73x o.ft^r tax
                                                  (1970 Abstract)
                                           (1-1)  On basis of fu-il at 2.68 miles per kwh.
                                         80

-------
Table 53.  Industry Costs and ProfLt Effects - 1958
      Total Anrvun 1 Abatement Co.sts - $ Million, 1963
S.I.C.
No.
-
20
208
22
24
26
28
29
2911
33
331
-
"
S.I.C.
N'o.
-
20
203
22
24
•26
28
29
2911
33
331
_
_
Industry Description
All Industries
Food and Kindred
Beverages
Textile Mills
Lumber and Wood
Paper and Allied
Chemical and Allied
Petroleum and Coal
Petroleum Refining
Primary Metals
Blast Furnace and Steel
Electric Power
All Industry Power
Profits Before Taxes,
— Wos 	 EX= 	 ! —
Practice Legislation
24,467 24,179
1,625 1,564
329 322
462 _452
117 114
750 731
3,012 2,891
3,356 3,331
3,321 3,297
3,411 3,373
2,040 2,019
4,789 4,398
29,256 28,576
196b "r.ictipa Ex-Legislation
834.5 1,123
146.8 208.4
15.6 22.2
55.3 65. S
6.7 9.7
62.2 81.6
127.7 248.9
96.0 120.5
91.0 116.7
293.4 326.4
191.8 213.4
58.5 449.7
8,930 1,573
Minimum Discharge
1,803
232.2
24.7
75.9
15.6
264.3
'415.8
168.9
163. S
499.1
326.3
449.7
2,258
*'lilli"n ioea Profits After Taxes, SMillion,
Discharge Discharge Practice
23,494 20,934 14,180
1,540 1,338 1,036
320 298 207
441 416 286
108 86.0 73.0
548 (356) 470
2,724 2,218 1,879
3,283 3,053 2,093
3,250 3,032 2,078
3,205 2,723 1,845
1,906 1,590 1,103
4,398 3,396 3,002
27,891 24,829 17,182
Ex- Minimum
Legislation. Pi 3 chare;
14,013 13,616
968 S53
206 201
280 273
71.1 67.4
458 343
1,804 1,699
2,077 2,047
2,063 2,034
1,327 1,734
1,092 1,031
2,757 2,757
16,7-70 16,373
Zero
Discharge
4,368
433.8
46.2
101.0
37.7,
1,168
921.7
393.9
2S1.5
981.2
641.5
952.0
5,320
1968
Zero
u Discharge
12,132
828
187
25S
53.7
(356)
1,384
1,907
1,897
1,473
860
2,442
14,574
               81

-------
The costs of 1968 practice were estimated as follows:


    Before-tax profit with control costs = $29,256
    Cost of pollution controls =           	893
    Before-tax profit with no control costs -
                                           $30,149
    After-tax profit  (x 17182/29256)=       17,706

    Taxes with no control costs            $12,443

After tax profits then on those facilities within each
industry which take in more than 20 million gallons annually
would be reduced as shown in Table 55, assuming 1968 after-
tax profits on sales with no compensating price increases;


          Table 55.  1968 After-Tax Profit Effects


                           After-tax profits as % of 1968 Experience
                                     Existing    Minimum     Zero
S.I.C,. No.       Industry          Legislation  Discharge  Discharge

           All Mfg. Industries        98.8        96.0       85.6
  20       Food and Kindred           96.2        94.7       82.3
 208       Beverages                  99.5        97.1       90.3
  22       Textile Mills              97.9        95.5       90.2
  24       Lumber and Wood            97.4        92.3       73.6
  26       Paper and Allied           97.4        73.0         0
  28       Chemical and Allied        96.0        90.4       73.7
  29       Petroleum and Coal         99.2        97.8       91.1
2911       Petroleum Refining         99.3        97.9       91.3
  33       Primary Metals             99.0        94.0       79.8
 331       Blast Furnace and
            Steel                     99.0        93.5       78.0
           Electric Power             91.8        91.8       81.3
           All Mfg. and Electric
            Power                     97.6        95.3       84.8


If it is assumed that a reduction of after-tax profits of
10 percent defines a significant cost, it might be concluded
that implementing existing legislation will not be a signi-
ficant burden, that implementing minimum discharge would be
a substantial burden only in the pulp and paper industry,
and that zero discharge would be of greatly variable but
significant cost impact in the other industry group.
                           82

-------
The economic effects of  zero discharge  vary widely between
industries.  The effects on after-tax profits,  assuming no
compensating price increases,  indicate  the relative impacts
on the various industries  in the  short  run, i.e., in the
time period until costs  could  be  recovered via  price
increases, and in the  long run if there is relatively less
ability to increase prices.  These effects are  shown in
Table 56 for the large water-using plants in  each industry.


Table 56. After-tax Profit Effects - Large Water Using Plants
                                         1968 After-Tax
S.I.C. No.        Industry             Profit Reduction  (%)

    26      Paper and Allied                 100.0
    24      Lumber and Wood                    26.4
    28      Chemical and Allied                26.3
   331      Blast Furnace  and  Steel            22.0
    33      Primary Metals                    20.2
       :     Electric Power                    18.7
    20      Food and Kindred                   17.7
    22      Textile Mills                       9.8
   208      Beverages                           9.7
    29      Petroleum and  Coal                 8.9
   2911      Petroleum Refining                 8.7
            All  Mfg. Industries                14.4
            All  Mfg. and Electric Power        15.2


Looking  at  the effects on  the  entire industries,  including
those facilities using relatively little water,  as,  shown
in Table 57.

Ordering the  data of Table 57  as to  relative impact and
expressing  the results as  percent of after-tax profit reduc-
tion yields the  data of Table  58.

The net  value of structures and  equipment in the manu-
facturing industries in 1968 was $92.3 billion in 1958.
dollars.  This represented about $109.6  billion in,1968
dollars.  Capital expenditures in 1968 totaled $20.3 billion;
depreciation  on  current plant  in that year totaled  $16.1
billion.  The value of electric  utility  plants in ,1968 was
$64.9 billion, increasing  to $71.5 billion in  1969.

The 1968 capital expenditures  required,  over and above
1968 practice would have been  as shown in Table 59.
                           83

-------
   Table 57.  After-tax Profit Effects - Entire Industries
                              1968 After-tax Profits  (zero discharge)
                                  (Millions of 1968 Dollars)
S.I.C. No.

    20
   208
    22
    24
    26
    28
    29
  2911
    33
   331
   Industry

Food and Kindred
Beverages
Textile Mills
Lumber and Wood
Paper and Allied
Chemical and Allied
Petroleum and Coal
Petroleum Refining
Primary Metals
Blast Furnace and
 Steel
Electric Power
Large
Water
Users
828
187
258
53.7
(356)
1384
1907
1897
1473
860
2442

Other
Plants
1029
184
395
206
588
1169
371
211
502
208
0

Industry
Total
1857
371
653
260
232
2553
2278
2108
1975
1068
2442
Percent
of
1968
91.3
94.9
95.9
93.2
21.9
83.8
92.5
92.1
84.1
81.5
81.3
    Table 58.  Profit Reductions due to Zero Discharge
S.I.C. No.

    26

   331
    28
    33
    20
  2911
    29
    24
   208
    22
                     Industry

               Paper and Allied
               Electric Power
               Blast Furnace and Steel
               Chemical and Allied
               Primary Metals
               Food and Kindred
               Petroleum Refining
               Petroleum and Coal
               Lumber and Wood
               Beverages
               Textile Mills
                             1968 After-Tax
                           Profit Reduction (%)

                                78.1
                                18.7
                                18.5
                                16.2
                                15.9
                                 8.7
                                 7.9
                                 7.5
                                 6.8
                                 5.1
                                 4.1
                          84

-------
   Table 59.  Capital Expenditures for Control in 1968
S.I.C.
  NO.       Industry

  20     Food and Kindred
  22     Textile Mills
  24     Lumber and Wood
  26     Paper and Allied
  28     Chemicals and Allied
  29     Petroleum and Coal
  33     Primary Metals
         Electric Power
         All Mfg. Industries

(1)   1968-69
                        Added Capital Cost, $ Million
                                            Capital
                      Minimum     Zero    Expenditure
                      Discharge Discharge 1968,$ million
                        311
                         54
                         27
                        452
                        935
                        241
                        772
                       1057
                       3090
               1039
                146
                101
               3431
               2649
                977
               2430
               3716
              11721
   1740
    691
    484
   1238
   2789
   1065
   3102
6561(1)
  20613
The above costs as percentages of the total annual capital
expenditures for new plant and equipment are shown in
Table 60.
Table 60. Pollution Control Costs as Percentages of Capital
                          Expenditures
S.I.C.
  NO.

  20
  22
  24
  26
  28
  29
  33
    Industry
Minimum Discharge  Zero Discharge
Food and Kindred
Textile Mills
Lumber and Wood
Paper and Allied
Chemicals and Allied
Petroleum and (bal
Primary Metals
Electric Power
All Mfg. Industries
        17.9
         7.8
         5.6
        36.5
        33.5
        22.6
        24.9
        16.1
        15.0
    7
    1
    9
    1
 59,
 21,
 20,
277,
 95.0
 91,7
 78.3
 56.6
 56.9
By the above measure, there are again great differences in
the impact of additional control costs between the various
industries, with the greatest effect again on the pulp and
paper industries.  By 1980, the required additional capital
investment for zero discharge would total $22.2 billion over
and above the cost of implementing existing legislation.
Assuming that these costs would be incurred in a 10-year
                          85

-------
period, about 8 percent of the annual expenditure for new
plant and equipment would be annually devoted to this
purpose.  The consequences of such expenditures would depend
to a large extent on whether or not they would add to
total capital expenditures or use money which would other-
wise be used to increase productive capacity.  The later
consequence would be significant.  To place this effect in
context, the expenditures forinew plant and equipment in the
manufacturing industries declined about 10.9% in 1949 from
1948, 5.2% in 1954 from 1953, and 5.0% in 1961 from I960,
periods closely related in short rises in unemployment and
to slowing economic growth as measured by'GNP in constant
dollars.  This is not to say that there was any direct
causative effects, but only to indicate that this magnitude
of change in capital expenditures is not insignificant.

Another way of looking at the costs involved is to compare
the added costs with a rise in wages.  For each industry
group, the 1968 cost increase due to wage increases of 1 to
10 percent are compared with pollution abatement costs in
Tables 61 and 62.
     Table 61.  Cost Increases Due to Wage Increases
S.I.C.
  No.      Industry

  20   Food and Kindred
 208   Beverages
  22   Textile Mills
  24   Lumber and Wood
  26   Paper and Allied
  28   Chemical and Allied
  29   Petroleum and Coal
2911   Petroleum Refining
  33   Primary Metals
 331   Blast Furnace and
        Steel
       Electric Power (1)
       All Mfg. Industries
1968 Wages
    Total
 Cost Increase-Wage % Rise
  1%      5%      10%
10607
1626
4770
3016
4794
7014
1292
1027
10620
106
16
48
30
48
70
13
10
106
     5411
    12935
   132902
  54
 129
1329
 530
  81
 239
 151
 240
 351
  65
  51
 531

 271
 647
6645
 1061
  163
  477
  302
  479
  701
  129
  103
 1062

  541
 1294
13290
(1)  229,000 production workers @ $3.72 per hour, 41.6 hours
     per week.
                          86

-------
  Table 62.   Added Control Costs vs. Wage Increase Costs
S.I.C.
  No.       Industry

  20     Food and Kindred          85
 208     Beverages                9.1
  22     Textile Mills           20.6
  24     Lumber and Wood          8.9
  26     Paper and Allied         202
  28     Chemical and Allied      288
  29     Petroleum and Coal      72.9
2911     Petroleum Refining      70.6
  33     Primary Metals           206
 331     Blast Furnace and        135
          Steel
  -      Electric Power           391
         All Mfg. Industries      973
  -      All Mfg. Industries
          and Power              1364
                             Annual Costs Over 1968 Practice
                                                       5%
                                Minimum      Zero     Wage
                               Discharge  Discharge   Rise
                                             287
                                            30.6
                                            45.7
                                            31.0
                                            1106
                                             794
                                             298
                                             286
                                             688
                                             450

                                             893
                                            3533

                                            4426
                       530
                        81
                       239
                       151
                       240
                       351
                        65
                        51
                       531
                       271

                       647
                      6645

                      7292
Minimum and zero discharge total annual costs over 1968
practice, from the above, correspond to the indicated rises
in wages in Table 63.


Table 63. Added Control Costs as Percentage Wage Increases
S.I.C.
  No.        Industry

  20     Food and Kindred
 208     Beverages
  22     Textile Mills
  24     Lumber and Wood
  26     Paper and Allied
  28     Chemical and Allied
  29     Petroleum and Coal
2911     Petroleum Refining
  33     Primary Metals
 331     Blast Furnace and
          Steel
         Electric Power
         All Mfg. Industries
         All Mfg. Industries
          and Power
Equivalent % Rise in Wages
  Minimum         Zero
 Discharge      Discharge
   0.80
   0.56
   0.43
   0.29
   4.21
   4.10
   5.61
   6.92
   1.94
   2.49

   3.02
   0.73

   0.94
                                                  2.71
                                                  1.89
                                                  0.96
                                                  1.03
                                                  23.0
                                                  11.3
                                                  22.9
                                                  28.0
                                                  6.48
                                                  8.30

                                                  6.90
                                                  2.66

                                                  3.03
                            87

-------
 The  preceeding  seem  to  fall  into  three  distinct groups with
 the  major  effects  evident  in the  paper  and  petroleum
 industries and  intermediate  effects  in  the  chemical, metals/
 and  electric  power industries.

 Short run  burdens  on industry may be in part reduced from
 relative profit positions  as shown in the data  on Table 64.
     Table 64.   Profit  Positions  of  Various  Industries
 S.I.C.
  No.        Industry

        All Mfg.  Industries
  20    Food and  Kindred
  22    Textile Mills
  24    Lumber  and  Wood
  26    Paper and Allied
  28    Chemical  and Allied
2911    Petroleum Refining
  33    Primary Metals
 331    Blast Furnace and
         Steel
Profit      Profit      Profit
on  Sales    on  Equity  on Equity
1970-        1970
\  of 1968   % of 1968     1970
                        9.3
                       10.8
                        5.1
                        5.9
                        7.0
                       11.5
                       11.0
                        6.9(2)
  50.9        50.6        4.0
78.4
96.2
61.3
47.2
72.3
86.8
86.9
72.4(1)
76.9
100.0
58.0
40.4
72.2
86.5
89.4
77.4(2)
 (1)   Weighted by volume of  sales  in steel,  copper,  aluminum
 based on large nonferrous companies.

 (2)   Weighted by volume of  sales  in steel and nonferrous
 metals.
 There are clearly current differences in profit positions
 with the food,  chemical,  and petroleum industries in the best
 relative positions.

 The data of Table 65. indicate to  what extent prices would
 have to be raised in order that the added costs of zero
 discharge be recovered via price  increases,  i.e., passing
 the costs to the customers.   All  except the  last item refer
 to the entire industry assuming the cost burden; the last
 item shows the cost  burden if assumed by the large water-
 using plants only.

 The consequences of  the implementation of zero discharge
 requirements may readily be determined from  the foregoing,
 assuming that implementation would  utilize the technology
 outlined and that costs would be  passed on to the ultimate
                            88

-------
                 Table 65.  Price Increases due to Zero Discharge
S.I.C.
No. 	
20
208
22
24
26
23
29
2911
33
331
-
_
1968
Value Added
In Water-Using
Industry Plants
Fopd and Kindred
Beverages
Textile Mills
Lumber and Wood
Paper and Allied
Chemical and Allied
Petroleum and Coal
Petroleum Refining
Primary Metals
Slast Furnace and Steel
Electric Power
All Mfg. Industries
12067
2835
3732
643
4968
16131
4612
4495
14798
9205
15859
125417
1963
Value of Added Cost
Shipnents for Zero
In Ir.civ.3try Ratio Discharge
78259
10031
21959
S257
22512
44326
23240
21395
44274
24733
19421
631911
6.
3.
5.
8.
4.
2.
5.
4.
2.
2.
1.
5.
485
538
887
176
531
779
039
760
992
637
225
038
287
30.6
45.7
31.0
1106
794
298
286
688
450
893
3533
Valuo o£
Value Added Shlpr.ar.tj
Kith Zero Kitn Zero
12354
2866
3778
674
6074
16925
4910
4781
15486
9635
16752
128950
80120
10141
22240
5510
27524
47032
24742
22756
46332
25<.!:
20515
649712
* Price
Increase
Zero
1.
1.
1.
1.
1.
1.
1.
1.
1.
1 .
1.
1.
02
01
01
05
22
05
06
06
05
05
06
03
All Mfg. Ind. and
 Power                    141276

Water-Using Mfg. and
 Power                    141276
651332     4.610     4426     1457D2     671737        1.03


297458     2.106     44?6     145702     306843        3.16
                                        89

-------
consumer.  In the short run, varying degrees of economic
hardship would be imposed on different industries.
Marginal production facilities would probably be closed
in these industries bearing the highest costs relative to
other production costs and in which profit margins have
been low.  Increased costs must, of course, be recovered
in the long run where such costs have a significant effect
on profits.

The ability to pass on increased costs via price increases
without loss in revenue depends upon the aggregate demand
function for a particular good, institutional factors such
as price controls and import restrictions, and the avail-
ability of substitutes and/or imports.  Whether or not the
assumed technology would be primarily determined by the
ability to reduce total water use and whether or not effluents
under minimum discharge could be reduced to less than assumed
here.

Whether or not zero discharge should be implemented at all
depends upon whether or not the improvement in the surface
waters are judged to be worth the cost as well as upon
whether or not the physical resources are available; the
effects on other parts of the environment are tolerable, and
the financial resources can be marshalled in such a way that
significant economic dislocations do not result in the long
run.

To some extent the effects of an increase in price due to
increased costs can be deduced from the supply and demand
characteristics of the market for a good.  In the classical
case, the analysis would be straightforward and can be illus-
trated by the instance of a tax added per unit of product.
In Figure 16, a relatively elastic demand curve (d-d)  and a
supply curve of unitary elasticity (s^ - s±) illustrate the
effect of a price increase, defining a new supply curve
(s2 - s2)•  In Figure 17, a similar effect is illustrated
with a relatively inelastic demand curve.  The more elastic
demand results in a shift of most of the tax backward to the
producer.  A more inelastic demand shifts most of the tax
forward to the consumer.

The effect of a nonproductive cost increase such as for poll-
ution control can theoretically be analyzed in the same way
as the tax increase.  The principal difficulties lie in that
the theoretical supply curve can hardly ever be constructed,
and that a demand curve constructed upon data over time is
only an approximation to the actual curve at one particular
time.
                          90

-------
Demand elasticity  is defined  as  the percent increase  in  the
quantity  (Q) divided by  the percent decrease in  the price
(P).  A usual convention is to use the average of  the two
quantities which define  each  change:
        E =  ~  -—  x (pi  + Pr>)/2
The demands  for most  products of the manufacturing  industries
are inelastic, i.e.,  the quantities of  goods  taken  are not
relatively responsive to price changes  insofar  as aggregate
demand is concerned.   This is to say that a cut in  price
will generally increase the quantity taken so little that
total revenue will  fall.   By the same token,  an increase in
price will generally  reduce the quantity  taken  so little
that total revenue  will increase.   The  quantities taken of
most products of  the  water-using manufacturing  industries
depend primarily  on the general level of  economic activity
rather than  upon  the  prices at which they are offered.  At
the 2-digit  S.I.C.  level there is little  substitution, thus
little opportunity  for the consumer to  switch to other
products.

The supply of most  products of these industries probably
depends more upon the percentage of productive  capacity being
utilized and upon the availability of imports than  on any
other factors.  Supply tends to be relatively elastic as
compared to  demand.  So long as there is  highly efficient,
unused productive capacity, supply is relatively elastic;
marginal capacity used to produce additional  quantities
wanted will  tend  to make supply more inelastic.  The avail-
ability of imports  will tend to increase  supply in  total,
i.e., shift  the entire supply curve to  the right, as these
industries attempt  to meet foreign competition.

Statistical  studies of demand for food  products indicates an
elasticity of about 0.3 and for steel industry  products as
"inelastic"  demand  (8,9), tending to substitute the above
qualitative  conclusions on demand elasticity.   If it is
assumed that production is in the most  efficient plants, most
of the added burden is passed on to the consumer.   As increased
quantities are taken  and supply becomes more  inelastic, the
costs are shifted more to the producer.

As the domestic supplier offers larger  quantities at higher
prices, the  availability of lower price substitutes or im-
ports increasingly  limits his share of  the market.  Figure
18 illustrates the  recent market situation for  steel in a
semi-quantitative manner, i.e., the data  are  for a  period
of 5 years and only approximate true supply and demand curves.
Domestic steel was  only taken to the extent of  96 million tons
                            91

-------
FIGURE 16,   MARKET EFFECTS2OF AN ADDED TAX WITH ELASTIC DEMAND
FIGURE 17,   MARKET EFFECTS # %\ ADDED TAX WITH INELASTIC DEHAND
                             92

-------
VO
C
o
-p
\
•c/i-
        g  150
        -H
        H
        Pn
                80  82   84  86   88   90   92   94   96   98   100  102   104   106  108  110  112  114  116  118

                            FIGURE 13,   DEMAND AND SUPPLY - STEEL INDUSTRY (1967-72)    Quantity, .minion  tons

-------
at a price of $204 per ton; the remaining steel consumed
was taken from lower priced imports.   The general case of
such a market situation is illustrated in Figure 19.
x
                     S /
                            SD,
                                SD
                                              V
                                                         SI


                                                         d
                        Q3   Q!                      Q2

      FIGURE 19,   INCREASED DOMESTIC COST AND IMPORTS
                          94

-------
Before the increase  in  the  cost  of  domestic  steel,  the
quantity Q1 of domestic steel  is taken  at  price P,.  The
quantity (Qz - Q:) of imported steel  is taken  at price
P2.  The revenue  to  domestic producers  is  (Pi  Q-, )  and to
importers is P?  (Q2  - Q ) .  After the increase in  the
cost of domestic  steel  ta non-productive cost) the  quan-
tity Q3 of domestic  steel is taken  at price  P..  The
smaller quantity  costs  the  consumer about  the  same  total
amount as the former larger quantity  and represents the
consumer's burden.   The domestic producer's  revenue falls
to Py 03 and represents the producer's  burden.  The
importer's revenue rises to P2 (Q2  -  Q3) and the importer,
of course, thus benefits from  the domestic cost increase.

The electric power industry, as  a regulated  public  utility,
can, in the long  run, shift such a  cost increase completely
to the consumer.  The available  quantity of  electric power
will be taken at  the regulated price  (generating capacity
being limited as  compared to -the  amount  wanted) ; the
consumer will pay more  for  less  total power, because the
requirement of cooling  towers  would reduce generating
capacity due to  the  higher  condenser  temperature.

Resource Requirements

Under the assumed zero  discharge technology, about  1,672
billion gallons  of water annually would be evaporated, i.e.,
the effluent volume  under minimum discharge  less the residual
brine.  At 1,000  BTU per Ib, the energy required would be
13.9 x 10^1 BTU  annually as of 1968,  increasing to  about
22.9 x 10 5 BTU  annually in 1980.  The  heat  energy  required
in 1980 would be  about  twice that rejected in  electric
power plant condensers  in 1980,  equal to about 33  percent
of the total U.  S. energy consumption in 1970, and  equal
to the total natural gas use in  the U.  S.  in 1969.

The 40 billion pounds per year of solids disposed  of on the
land in 1980 would be about 65 percent  of  the  total salt
produced as a product in the U.  S.  in 1969.  At a  density
of 48 Ibs per cu  ft', the 40 billion pounds of  solids would
occupy 838 million cu ft, i.e.,  about 19,000 acre  feet, or
about 30 square miles.

The combustible material to be incinerated and thus dis-
charged to the air amounts  to  220 million  pounds per year,
mostly expressed  as  B.O.D., thus equivalent  to 290  million
pounds of CO- and 20 million pounds of  CO  at 90 percent
combustion efficiency.   The carbon  monoxide  emissions would
be about 0.5 percent of that resulting  from  stationary
fuel combustion  in the  U. S. in  1969.
                           95

-------
The 1,672 billion gallons of water to be evaporated annually
in 9,402 establishments would require that number of
distillation units averaging 500,000 gpd, and would require
some 5,000 deep wells for disposals of brine where this
method is feasible.  There are presently about 30,000
oil wells annually drilled; therefore, 5,000 wells would
not represent a major problem.  The peak production of
power boilers in 1969 was valued at $645 million and
represented steam productions 300 million pounds per hour.
The total value of fabricated products in S.I.C. 344 in
1969 was $11.26 billion.  The evaporator capacity required
in 1968 was thus equivalent to above 5 times the power
boiler production capacity, since boiler manufacturers
have been at production capacity for several years.   A
waste treatment market estimated at only about $150 million
has been a major marketing target of a large company pro-
ducing evaporators.  If reverse osmosis were a feasible
alternative to evaporation, power requirements at 35 KW-hr
per 1,000 gallons would total 58.5 million KW-hr per year..
This is about 50 percent of the electric energy generated
by industrial plants and about 5 percent of that generated
by electric utilities in 1968.
                           96

-------
                        SECTION XI

                     ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

The advice and guidanc'e provided by Mr. Donald H. Lewis,
Mr. Paul Gerhardt, and Dr. Roger Don Shull of the
Environmental Protection Agency are acknowledged with
sincere thanks.

The courtesy of the National  Council of the Paper Industry
for Air and Stream Improvement and the American Petroleum
Institute in meeting with  Project personnel to discuss
problems of minimum discharge is appreciated.

The credit information regarding financing of pollution
control equipment, provided by Mellon Bank, N.A., Western
Pennsylvania National Bank and the Union National Bank
of Pittsburgh  is  appreciated.
                           97

-------
                        SECTION XII

                         REFERENCES

 1.   "The 500 Largest U. S. Industrial Corporations,"
     FORTUNE, LXXXV, 5, May, 1972.

 2.   Federal Power Commission, "Steam-Electric Plant
     Construction Cost and Annual Production Expenses,
     Twenty-Second Annual Supplement-1969,"  Washington,
     D.  C., January, 1971.

 3.   Council on Environmental Quality and Environmental
     Protection Agency, "The Economic Impact of Pollution
     Control - A Summary of Recent Studies,"  Washington,
     D.  C., March, 1972.

 4.   Bureau of Domestic Commerce,  "U. S. Industrial Out-
     look 1972 with Projections to 1980,"  Washington,
     D-  C.

 5.   Colberg, M. R. , Forbush, D. R., and Whitaker, G. R. ,
     Jr.,  "Business Economics, Principles and Cases,"
     Richard D. Irwin, Inc., Homewood, Illinois (1964)'.

 6.   Gregory, R. G. ,  "U. S. Imports and Internal Pressure
     of Demand, "  American Economic Review, LXI, 1, p.  28
     March, 1971,

 7.   Fisher, A. C. , Krutilla, J. V., and Cicchetfci/ C. J. ,
     "The Economics of Environmental Preservation,"
     American Economic Review, LXII, 4, p. 605 September,
     1972.

 8.   Bain, Joe S., "Price and Production Policies,"  A
     Survey of Contemporary Economics - Volume I,  Richard
     D.  Irwin, Inc., Homewood, Illinois, p. 139 (.1964).

 9.   Mack, Ruth P.,  "Economics of Consumption,"  A Survey
     of Contemporary Economics - Volume II, Richard D.
     Irwin, Inc., Homewood, Illinois, p. 39 (1952).

10.   Stigler, George J., "The Theory of Price," The Mac-
     Millan Company, New York   (1952) .

11.   Federal Water Pollution Control Administration, "Deep
     Wells for Industrial Waste Injection in the United
     States - Summary of Data," Cincinnati, Ohio, November,
     1967.
                            99

-------
12.  Federal Water Pollution Control Administration, "The
     Cost of Clean Water," Washington, D. C., January 10,
     1968.

13.  The Institute for Environmental Quality, "An Over-
     view of the Technology and the Economics of Indus-
     trial Heat Rejection and Thermal Pollution Abatement,"
     Chicago, Illinois, March, 1971.

14.  Federal Water Pollution Control Administration,
     "Industrial Waste Guide on Thermal Pollution," Pacific
     Northwest Water Laboratory, Corvallis, Oregon,
     September, 1968.

15.  U. S. Atomic Energy Commission, News Release, 3_, 30,
     Washington, D. C., July 26, 1972.

16.  Environmental Protection Agency, "Inorganic Chemicals
     Industry Profile," Washington, D. C.,  July, 1971.

17.  Aries, R. S., and Newton, R.  D., "Chemical Engineering
     Cost Estimation," McGraw-Hill Book Company, New York
     (1955).

18.  Popper, Herbert, "Modern Cost-Engineering Techniques,"
     McGraw-Hill Book Company, New York  (1970).

19.  Parker, F. L. , and Krenkel, P. A., "Engineering Aspects
     of Thermal Pollution," Vanderbilt University Press,
     Nashville*(1969).

20.  Anon., "How to Save on Pollution Outlays," Chemical
     Week, November 10, 1971, p. 65.

21.  Rapier, P. M., "Ultimate Disposal of Brines from
     Municipal Waste Water Renovation," Burns and Roe,  Inc.,
     FWQA Contract No. 14-12-495 (17070 DJW).

22.  Koenig, L., "Disposal of Saline Water Conversion Brines,"
     OSW R & D Progress Report No.  20, 1958.

23.  Koenig, L., "Ultimate Disposal of Advanced^Treatment
     Waste," Parts l*and 2 US.P.H.S. AWTR-3, October, 1963.

24.  Office of Business Economics,  U. S. Department of
     Commerce, "1971 Business Statistics,"  Washington,  D. C.,
     October, 1971.
                          100

-------
                        SECTION XIII




                        APPENDICES




                                                       Page




A.  FACTORS DETERMINING TECHNOLOGY UTILIZATION         102




B.  INDUSTRY ATTITUDES TOWARD MINIMUM DISCHARGE
                            101

-------
                        APPENDIX A

        FACTORS DETERMINING TECHNOLOGY UTILIZATION

This phase of the project to evaluate the Economic
Feasibility of Universal Requirements of Minimum
Practicable Industrial Waste Load Discharges was devoted
to research and study of the determinants of the adop-
tion and utilization of available technology, as dis-
tinct from the degree to which it has in fact been adop-
ted and utilized.  Whereas the latter approach would
constitute an instant picture of the present state of
affairs, it sheds no light on the factors which brought
it about or the pressures operating to accelerate or
retard the rate of adoption of available technology in
the future.  The former approach, on the other hand,
provides an understanding of the motivating factors which
have led to the present state and which can be relied
upon to influence the rate 6f adoption in the future.

These determinants or factors, both positive and nega-
tive, have been identified, and an attempt has been made
to evaluate the importance of each in isolation, in its
affect on management decisions concerning the adoption of
available technology.
                               i

The conclusions and results of this phase of the Project
are based, for the most part, on data collected in an
earlier study conducted by Frederick D. Buggie, a Data-
graphics associated consultant.  Secondary data supple-
menting this material included "Industry Cleanup Actions
in Progress", by the National Industrial Pollution Control
Council; "A Nationwide Survey of Environmental Protection",
by the Wall Street Journal; recent polls conducted by
Louis Harris & Associates; and selected articles and re-
ports from business, technical and professional journals.

American industry has not done their part in controlling
pollution, according to 57% of the respondents to a 1971
poll by Louis Harris & Associates.  However, 60% of the
general public who responded to the poll indicated that
they felt industry had installed the latest improvements
in equipment, generally.  The results indicate a deterio-
ration in industry's reputation for adopting the latest
technology for pollution control, since five years earlier
when a similar poll yielded figures of 42% and 89%,
respectively.
              *
This "image" problem has become increasingly recognized
by business executives and in fact appears to constitute
one of the three fundamental positive factors motivating
                          102

-------
industry to adopt and utilize  available technology for
pollution control.  In an  independent survey of execu-
tives conducted this year, almost two-thirds of the
respondents said they believe  that their corporate image
has suggered from adverse  publicity and slanted news
reporting.  There are indications of a certain amount of
resentment and despondency in  the attitudes of business-
men regarding their pollution-control reputation.  A 1971
survey by The Wall Street  Journal showed that only 35%
of the respondents felt  that even their most impressive
environmental achievements would improve their image among
consumers, and a substantially-lower proportion thought
it would favorably influence stockholders and the finan-
cial community.

But there is not much question that the "image" problem
does serve as a spur to  businessmen to adopt available
pollution-control technology so that they can then promote
and publicize what they  are doing to improve the environ-
ment  (or at least minimize its degradation), among the
various publics on which they  rely for long-run success.

The second major factor  influencing industry to utilize
available pollution-control technology is seen as "regu-
latory pressure".  Those charged with the responsibility
of enforcing water-pollution control have by and large
succeeded in calling industry's attention to the problem
of water pollution, and  convincing management that some-
thing must be done to control  it.  The Federal efforts
 (including permit application, voluntary questionnaires,
publicity concerning enforcement actions and administrative
decisions by E.P.A., and the activities of  the E.P.A.
Regional Officials) in combination with, in some cases, an
extremely active effort  by state and local  regulatory
authorities, have led to a situation wherein practically no
manufacturer is now unaware of pressures to control indus-
trial waste discharges,  and not persuaded that some kind
of management response is  necessary.  As a  matter of fact,
over half the respondents  to a recent survey indicated that
they had been subject to overlapping and duplicative
regulatory requirements  by various levels of authority.
But the point is, "regulatory  pressure" has had fundamental
influence on management  to seek out the available technology
for controlling pollution.

The third positive factor  — the only other observed major
influence on industry to adopt and utilize  available tech-
nology for pollution control — could be called  "corporate
conscience", or management's desire to do what is right.
Whether such a corporate policy derives from a concern for
                           103

-------
corporate image, or from fear of prosecution by the regu-
lators, or pragmatic long-run self-interest, or simply the
American ethic, is a matter for speculation.  Regardless,
it is a discernible force motivating industry to adopt
available technology for controlling pollution.  Industry
attitudes, from the perspective of a recent survey, clearly
seem to be cooperative.  Excerpts from comments volunteered:

     "...I believe that both government and industry
     have a responsibility to clean it up together..."

     "We believe we have a responsibility to control these
     (dangerous components in our effluent)..."

     "The present crunch should not surprise anyone who
     has had his eyes open for the last 15 years."

     "Too long have we lived like slobs	..." •

These comments typified the underlying current of the
general attitude of polluters toward the task of improving
the environment.  The results of the survey turned up wide-
spread acceptance of the desirability of adopting available
pollution-control technology.  The overall impression
created by comments of respondents was one of a willingness
to do their best ultimately to solve the problem.

On the other side, there are several negative factors
influencing management decisions at this point on the adop-
tion and utilization of available technology for pollution
control.  These negative determinants, mostly uncovered
in the survey conducted earlier this year, lead one to two
fundamental conclusions:  1)  They are transitory.  The
individual manufacturers will eventually discontinue post-
ponement actions  (i.e. stop foot-dragging) and take positive
measures to adopt current pollution-abatement technology.
2)  In most instances, it is apparent that something can
be done, in time, to eliminate or ameliorate these negative
factors.  This may constitute the most useful practical
purpose served by the present study:  To serve as a guide
to the areas in which effort can be devoted effectively to
spur the earlier adoption of current technology for pollu-
tion control.

One qualification to these two conclusions 	 in cases
where nothing can be done and an individual plant must be
closed (or operations cannot be expanded) in the judgment
of management responsible for those operations, on the macro-
economic scale over time, it will be found that those
manufacturers which have survived will have adopted current
pollution-control technology.
                          104

-------
Eleven of the companies  surveyed had already closed 43
plants affecting 1,434 employees;  eight companies were
considering closing nine marginal  plants affecting a total
of 3)200 employees; and  three  companies had decided not
to expand, canceling plans  for new plants with probably
between 800 and 1,600 new jobs.

A consultant to the mining  industry foresees that "up
to 20" marginal facilities  in  that industry may be shut
down.  The American Paper Institute recently claimed
that 40 paper mills were closed during 1971 because of
environmental problems;  reportedly some 160 iron foundries
have ceased operations over the past three years; and the
Department of Commerce reports 60  plant closings in other
industries, as a  result of environmental pollution-control
pressures.

It should come as no surprise  to anyone that marginal
firms will be unable to  survive in the face of sudden, forced
outlays of cash for nonproductive  assets.  The social cost
and inequities of frictional dislocations caused by man-
datory environmental pollution-control requirements are
inherent in restructuring the  priorities of our society.

In this setting then, the negative determinants, or the
factors discouraging the immediate adoption of available
pollution-control technology   by industry, many of which are
inter-related, will be enumerated:

 (1)  The cost of pollution-abatement equipment.

Aggregate costs to certain  industries for controlling their
pollution to current required  levels has been recently
dealt with by contractors to the President's Council on
Environmental Quality.   Comparative costs of alternative
methods for controlling  pollution  will be dealt with else-
where in this study.  The-main point we wish to make here
is that the high cost of pollution control, as perceived
by management, is a factor  discouraging the immediate
adoption by industry of  the available technology.  Two-thirds
of the surveyed companies indicated that they are experiencing
"serious cost problems"  stemming from current pollution-
control regulations.  One-third felt that it is necessary for
pollution-control equipment manufacturers to reduce!their
prices.  This gives rise to the thought that when pollution
control systems are purchased  in greater quantity, prices
will surely come down due to economics of scale made
possible thereby.  But,  on  the-other hand, there has been
recent speculation in the press  (via. Business Week, March
18, 1972, p. 20) that the result will be just the opposite -
                           105

-------
that increased demand in the face of fixed supply will tend
to increase prices.  The answer will lie in a study of the
specific cost structures of firms in the pollution-control
equipment industry, barriers to entry into the industry,
the competitive climate, and cross-elasticities of demand
as among alternative pollution-control devices.

(2)  Competitive pressures

Manufacturers are  (rightly) sensitive to cost advantages
which their competitors may be able to gain.  In the survey,
39% of the respondents indicated they are having competition
problems, and 26% felt that some of their competitors are
located in geographical areas where they are subject to less
stringent pollution-control regulations.  Foreign competition
is of particular concern, for some industries, including
the mining industry.  In addition to spatial competitive
disadvantage, temporal competitive disadvantage was of
major concern.  For example, "Competitors with more modern
mills can achieve new pollution goals at less cost."  The
president of one prominent consulting engineering firm was
especially concerned about competitive parity in the steel
industry between new mills which could design in available
pollution-control technology, and old mills which faced the
"extensive retrofit problem" in meeting the necessary stan-
dards for the industry.  He suggested more R & D by the
Federal Government and construction grants to industry for
retrofit of old plants.

(3)  Economic conditions

This factor is intrinsically neither positive nor negative.
It may explain in part why available technology for pollu-
tion control has not been adopted in the past couple of
years; but it may also contribute toward greater utilization
of available technology in the next couple of years ('72-
'74).  The point must simply be made that it is a factor
which is to be taken into account.

(4)  Moving target  (no. 1)

An attitude of incredulousness has been exhibited in some
quarters concerning existing and proposed pollution-control
regulations.  There is the feeling that they are not realis-
tic and that reasonable compromise will eventually prevail.
In the words of a management representative of one industry,
there is a need "to determine standards divorced from
environmental hysteria and political gamesmanship, that
would represent not the maximum achievable reduction in
pollution, but a degree of pollution abatement commensurate
with the maximum social good."  This feeling of impending
                          106

-------
change in the ground  rules  is  fostered  and  reinforced by
perceived confusion,  complexity,  duplication, conflicts,
and inconsistency  in  the  present  regulations and enforce-
ment activities  of the  various pollution-control regulatory
authorities.  In the  survey,  45%  of  the respondents saw
inconsistency on the  part of  E.P.A.,  and slightly more than
one-third complained  of changing  policies by State regulatory
authorities.  In the  case of  13%  of  the companies, there
has been what could be  called  "counterproductive impact"
of such regulatory efforts.   These firms have assumed the
posture that they  will  just sit tight until the situation
is clarified and they are told exactly  what to do.

 (5)  Overkill

In some instances, there  has  been rigid all-or-none approach
by the regulatory  authorities, a  lack of pragmatism, a
failure to  understand that  degree of perfection and time
delay represent  trade-offs.   One  manufacturer reported that
he offered  to adopt measures  that would result in a 50%
reduction in pollution  immediately,  but that this was
rejected as unacceptable  because  it  fell short of the require-
ments, and  therefore  considerable delay ensued before any
pollution abatement at  all  was achieved.  This is regarded
as an atypical case.  The implementation plans and compliance
schedules are designed  for  just the  purpose of bringing
polluters gradually up  to required standards over a reason-
able period of time.  But the  point  remains:  Excessive
rigidity can retard the adoption  of  available technology.
And the corollary, insistence  on  the adoption of latest
available technology  can  forestall the  utilization of immed-
iate temporary expedients,  perhaps to the detriment of the
environment.

 (6)  Absolute unavailability  of products embodying avail-
able technology.

The need for pollution-control equipment manufacturers to
improve their products  was  expressed by 47% of the survey
respondents.  As one  manufacturer put it,  "most abatement
equipment manufacturers are municipally-oriented; better
equipment for industrial  waste treatment needs to be
developed." The need for improved maintenance service and
response to complaints  regarding  operation  of equipment,
by manufacturers was  also expressed.

 (7)  Moving target (no. 2)

In some cases, pollution-control  systems are being developed
to incorporate the latest technology, and in other areas,
the technology itself is  advancing.   There  is some irreducible
                           107

-------
minimum reasonable time period required for planning,
budgeting, engineering specifying, purchasing, installa-
tion, and start-up of new pollution control systems
embodying the latest available technology.  Time must be
allowed to study  and install process changes and/or new
pollution control systems, between the time the avail-
able technology is discovered and the time it can be
utilized by the manufacturer.  And after it is installed,
it is reasonable to permit a utilization period  (5 years
?) during which the newly-installed equipment can be
depreciated/worn out/used up, notwithstanding continuing
advances in technology which may £ake place during that
period.  In the words of one industrial executive, "We
must remove the threat of having to replace the best of
today's equipment with the new equipment of a few years
hence.  Some longer planning period, say 11 years, must
be allowed."  It is clear that the anticipation of a
significant advance in pollution-abatement technology
can, of itself, immobilize prospective users of currently-
available technology.

(8)  Lack of Information

Although the technology may be adequate and the products
and systems incorporating it may be available, ignorance
of their applicability may deter adoption by those most
requiring them.  Some 45% of the survey respondents
indicated the need for more information concerning pollu-
tion control technology.  About one-third desired an
advisory service on call, and a like number of those
surveyed felt that seminars held on a regional level would
be helpful in disseminating the needed information.  Some
30% thought that more dialogue among firms in their own
industry, including case histories on typical problem
solutions, would be salutory, provided that such coopera-
tion would not run afoul  of the anti-trust laws.  We
believe that the Technology Transfer program of E.P.A.
has an important role to play in this area and can, through
its efforts, encourage the adoption of available technology
for pollution control.

(9)  Truth in Advertising

Closely related to the preceding factor, is the difficulty
of evaluating among alternative pollution-abatement systems
which are promoted by their manufacturers.  It has been
found that in some cases, the advertisers' puffery and mis-
leading claims only add to the confusion, fallacious
assumptions, and invalid conclusions, rather than eluci-
dating the proper course of action.
                          108

-------
(10)   Safety in Numbers

Some resentment has continually cropped up, in arguments
by\polluters, that there are inequities in the treatment
of municipalities and industrial manufacturers by the
enforcement officials.  This is simply a red herring,
albeit oft used as a tactic to support delay in adopting
available technology for the control of pollution.

(11)  Sidestep

A very small proportion of manufacturers are begging the
question altogether, by either tying in to a public
treatment facility, or by hiring a private contractor
to handle their waste.  This may be practicable from the
polluter's  standpoint and desirable from society's stand-
point, but  nonetheless must be recognized as an avenue
available to avoid  the adoption of current available
pollution-control technology.
                           109

-------
                        APPENDIX B

        INDUSTRY ATTITUDES TOWARD MINIMUM DISCHARGE

Some general observations concerning industry's attitude
toward minimum discharge can be made on the basis of
interviews and discussions with representatives of
industry, consultants, and equipment vendors.

It has been tacitly assumed by many people that if and
when the effluent quality required for discharge from
an industrial operation is equal to or better than the
previously used water supply or the quality of water
required for that industry operation, reuse of the effluent
would follow almost automatically.  The interviews that
have been held and the progress ,of current litigation in
Illinois indicate that this is far from the case.

The first principal reason for resistance to the concept
of minimum discharge, as opposed to terminal treatment,
is the claim that no demonstrable benefit can be shown
insofar as) water quality affecting uses is concerned.
This is apparently a sincerely held belief on the part
of industry representatives.  It is inherent ,in the water
quality standard concept which implicitly says that the
assimilative capacity of the surface waters, up to the
tolerable limits of any contaminant for specific uses,
should be available to the discharger of waste -water
effluents.

Litigation in Illinois has been based on the State's conten-
tion that nothing less than minimum discharge, i.e.,
recirculation and blowdown treatment, is acceptable.  In
most of these cases, the average quality of the process
waste water effluent would be as good or better than that
of the intake water or equal to or better than the water
quality required for use when agreed-upon treatment is
installed.  Pumping and distribution facilities would have
to be added and cooling would generally be required for
reuse.  The Plaintiffs here are not seeking any restric-
tions on the once-through use of indirect cooling water.
The Defendents have taken the position that only a court
order will force them to recycle the treated process waste
water and this attitude is apparently based upon the
additional costs involved.  There has been no argument that
reuse is not technologically feasible.  A very likely
additional motive, however,  is the fear that a precedent
set here will be noted in other plants where present treat-
ment is not nearly as good.   That other comparable indus-
trial plants in the Lower Lake Michigan region have insti-
tuted measures similar to those demanded by the Plaintiffs
apparently has no significance insofar as these Defendents
are concerned.
                          110

-------
In nearly all cases, the age of  the plant seems to be the
second most important point.   It is maintained that the
cost of instituting reuse  systems in old plants'is pro-
hibitive due to lack of space  and the complexities of
pumping and piping changes; and  that had reuse systems
been mandated prior to the construction of terminal treat-
ment facilities, construction  layouts would have been
different and presumably less  extensive treatment systems
installed.  An additional  factor of importance is undoubt-
edly the reluctance of those responsible for the design
and installation of present facilities to go again to
management and say that more money must be spent; this
seems to be akin to saying that  there was no foresight of
increasingly stringent regulations.  There is little
indication of militant resistance to minimum discharge
facilities in plants under construction.

The consent decree in the  case of Illinois vs. U. S. Steel,
South Chicago Works indicates  that the change to minimum
discharge in old plants with terminal treatment is neither
impossible nor impractical.  Not only is this particular
plant old and large, but the required construction was in
a sandy soil on the lakeshore  and involved extensive
tunneling.

In the opinions of some consultants, resistance to any
change, the unwillingness  to assume any additional real or
imagined problems or to do anything that might conceivably
interfere with production, the lack of knowledge of alter-
native technology, and the costs involved are the reasons
why once-through use with  terminal treatment is so stub-
bornly advocated by industry.  The engineering profession
seems to be at least partially guilty of perpetuating ter-
minal treatment systems, i.e., recommending and designing
systems on the basis of past,  tried-and-true, similar
systems.  This may be as much  due to the lack of knowledge
of the alternative technology  as to the specification of
terminal treatment by the  client in the opinion of many.

The installation of reuse  systems is frequently blamed for
production problems.  A "new"  factor such as this undoubt-
edly provides a convenient scapegoat for plant operators
who must always explain any production problems to their
superiors.  Many reported  "failures" of reuse systems can
be traced to this sort of  situation.  There is also the at
least implied resentment of "changing the rules in the
middle of the game."  It is perhaps a moot question as to
whom is most guilty of the lack  of foresight: Industry or
those responsible for regulations. Industry, at its own
insistence, has been part  of the business of formulating_
regulations; it is hardly  credible to now maintain that it
                          111

-------
had no foreknowledge of things to come.

Several consultants and equipment vendors felt that pollu-
tion control measures costing more than 20% of profits
would be regarded as prohibitive; investment of 10% of
profits would be considered normal.  The concept of
minimum discharge would find greater acceptance if blow-
down of 5-20% of the recirculation rate could go to
municipal sewers.  Capital costs and the reluctance to
change are the primary objections to reuse systems.  The
availability of loans that would not reduce borrowing power
for production facilities would greatly accelerate reuse
systems acceptability.

Interviews with loan officers at three major Pittsburgh
banks indicate that loans for pollution control facilities
are generally available to good credit risks and such loans
are based upon general financial position as are any other
loans.  Such equipment is useless as collateral, except
for some package-type plants which can be easily removed
and sold.  The largest commercial bank regards pre-treat-
ment facilities and post-treatment facilities in much
the same way, i.e., as overhead costs which reduce profit-
ability.  This bank, however, frequently will loan money
for such purposes as a community service gesture when the
project, considered on its own, is not regarded as a good
risk.  The other two banks regard pre-treatment facilities
as production equipment and will lend money as for any
production facility.  Generally, good credit risks can
borrow money for any purpose; marginal risks generally
have to justify loans on ttie basis of -expected return and
can only borrow a portion of the cost.

Personnel interviewed at the American -Petroleum Institute
were able to offer certain generalizations regarding the
practical application of various water pollution control
techniques by the refining industry that seemed to offer
insight into the factors influencing management attitudes
toward minimum waste water discharge.

The first, and most basic, of these is consideration of the
difference in economic aspects of pollution control in the
petroleum industry as between the integrated and non-
integrated producing and refining companies.

In the petroleum industry an integrated company is one that
owns its own production, transportation, refining and,
usually, marketing facilities.  In the case of refineries,
the non-integrated unit is usually the independent refiner
who owns only the refinery and purchases his feedstock from
the producing companies at competitive prices.  He may, or
may not, have marketing facilities at the consumer level.
                          112

-------
These two categories of  companies  are  in very different
positions regarding large  capital  and/or operating
expenditures.  Thus, while a  given pollution control
process may be technically feasible for all refineries,
it may also be economically difficult  for a great many
presently operating, non-integrated refineries.

The differences  in these two  categories of petroleum
operations also  shows  up in the  organization of respon-
sibility for originating and  implementing pollution con-
trol measures.   In general, the  integrated companies make
all major final  decisions  at  the corporate management
level.  Each integrated  company, of which there are
approximately 30 in the  United States, now has a manage-
ment environmental control group operating at corporate
headquarters and reviewing and supervising the installation
and operation of pollution control facilities at the corpo-
ration's individual refineries.  The non-integrated
 (approximately 1,500)  refineries generally have key deci-
sions regarding  such facilities  made by the plant owner
or manager.  In  both cases, however, the practice of using
consultants for  final  design  and installation of any
pollution control system is nearly universal.  The reason
for this practice is primarily political, i.e., it puts a
neutral and presumably,  objective, third party between the
refinery and the various regulatory bodies.

There are significant  differences  in management's willing-
ness to install  pollution  control  in new plants as opposed
to older, existing plants. When designing new refineries,
the pollution control  facilities,  in general, are designed
to the maximum limits  of current technology, irrespective
of existing treatment  standards  or limitations prescribed
by law.  In older refineries  the installation of such
facilities is usually  geared  to  minimum, short-range com-
pliance.  The complexities of piping systems in refinery  ^
processes usually makes  any modification in existing fluid-
flow systems expensive.  The  technology for high-level
treatment, or closed-systems  design, may also be expensive.
Since the rate of obsolescence is  usually high in refining
installation, the management  of  older  refineries often
finds that high-level  or reuse treatment systems require
capital expenditures  involved that will require, say twenty
years to recover when  the  refinery itself may only have a
projected remaining life of ten  years.  In such cases, both
the initial cost of the  system and the operating costs may
be critical to the decision-making process.

Due to the intensive  level of competition between petroleum
product producers at the level of  the  ultimate consumer,
                          113

-------
it becomes almost impossible for the non-integrated refiner
to pass along these increased costs, in the form of price
increases, to the consumer.  Furthermore, the small refiner
is unable to purchase his feedstock at any significantly
lower price to compensate for the increased cost.  On the
other hand, the integrated company often can:   (1)  balance
increased cost at one particular facility against other
higher profitability operations  (2)  has some control over
the actual cost of his feedstock supply, and  (3)  can
often influence the overall market sufficiently to pass
his increased costs on in the form of product price
increases.  In consideration of the foregoing marketing
and economic factors, it is the opinion of people in the
petroleum industry that pollution control requirements will
lead to the disappearance of the non-integrated refiners
in the next few years.  This will probably occur through
mergers and acquisitions between the two categories,
rather than by individual plant shutdowns caused by finan-
cial stress, thus hopefully avoiding serious employment dis-
location during the period.  This situation will, of course,
be accelerated by the addition of new environment restric-
tions on lead and sulfur in the finished product.  These
restrictions will add a great deal to the total cost of
rennovating old plants to meet all the new environmental
restrictions.  Given the relatively narrow profit margins
of the independent refiner, it does appear as though the
combination of the factors cited will probably, in the
near future, result in a considerable realignment of the
traditional processing and marketing phases of the petroleum
industry.

The industry is currently spending about 20 to 25% of new
plant cost on various pollution control systems.  One case
has shown a system cost of 36% of new plant cost but this
was exceptional.  The relation between pollution control
costs and plant cost varies widely in the case of older
plants.  And it will usually appear as an excessive percen-
tage if current equipment costs are applied to original
plant costs.

A more practical relationship, in the case of these older
plants, is to calculate the cost of pollution control sys-
tems against the percentage of profitability that has been
established by past plant operation.   This is the approach
most plant managers are using either, consciously or sub-
consciously, and it does appear to give them a more rea-
listic base from which to estimate funds available for
installation and operation of control facilities.

In general one might say that, for new plants, an invest-
ment over 10% of plant cost would be considered significant,
an investment of 20 to 25% would be normal, and in investment
                          114

-------
in excess of 35% would be considered excessive or prohibi-
tive by most corporate managers.

However, for older plants the percentage figures will
vary widely, in attempting  to relate pollution control
facilities cost to plant cost.  The determining factor
being, of course, the particular numbers used to repre-
sent "plant cost".  Obviously,  in most cases, relating
current pollution control system cost to old plant original
cost will make the pollution system cost up as an excess-
ive percentage figure of "plant cost".

In relating pollution control cost to profitability one
gets a little better picture of the relationship between
system cost and the old plant management's "ability to
pay" for the system.  In general, the "old plant" profit
per gallon of finished product  will average between .05
cents and  .075 cents across the total product line pro-
ducer per year.  Thus, if total pollution control system
initial cost and operating  cost run over about 5% of this
figure, for very long, the  older non-integrated plant will
be in serious trouble.

Furthermore, this problem does  not appear to be greatly
helped by  low-cost, long-term loan availability in many
such cases.  If we assume a period of 10 to 12 years as
the breakdown point between new and old plants and an
average refinery life of 25 years, it follows that a 20-
year loan, for example, would be of little use to manage-
ment for the construction of pollution control facilities
in a non-integrated 12 year old plant.

For this reason, the non-integrated older refineries would
frequently not be able to avail themselves of such loans.
On the other hand, the larger integrated companies would
probably make use of such loans but, in most cases, do
not really need them to survive.

Insofar as the A.P.I, is concerned, an effective environ-
mental protection program for the petroleum refining indus-
try must balance several important factors in order to
achieve optimal overall social  benefit.  Among these are:

1.  Maximum protection of the natural environment.
2.  Maximum protection of total current refinery capacity
    in the U. S.  ("a country that runs on oil cannot
    afford to run out.")
3.  Minimum economic dislocation in terms of unemploy-
    ment or increase of product prices.
4.  Maintenance of availability of adequate water supply.
                           115

-------
The views of industry representatives to the National
Council of the Paper Industry for Air and Stream
Improvement were sought at a meeting of this group in
New York.  The opinion was expressed that the problems
of the pulp and paper industry are primarily due to the
fact that it is an extractive industry whose technology
is heavily dependent upon water as the extractive medium.
Additionally, various segments of the industry are really
quite different in water use, potential contaminant loads,
process water requirements, and financial positions.

The contaminants in the industry's waste waters fall into
three categories:  suspended solids, soluble organics,
and esthetically objectionable characteristics such as
color.  Insofar as the reuse of paper is concerned, it
can be reused in its own grade or down-graded to a lower
grade, but cannot be reused to produce a higher grade or
class.  These grades can be classified as follows from
the highest to lowest grades:

1.  Tissue and bond paper
2.  Magazine and coated paper
3.  Newsprint and paperboard
4.  Roofing felt

The production of de-inked pulp creates by far the most
severe pollution problem in the pulp and paper industry.

For every one-hundred pounds of waste paper entering a
de-inking plant, seventy-five pounds of de-inked pulp is
produced; i.e., twenty-five pounds of broken fibers, ink,
and foreign materials must be disposed of.   Most of this
waste is as a watery sludge which must be thickened and
dried prior to incineration.  The B.O.D. in the waste from
a de-inking plant is 110 pounds per ton of de-inked pulp
versus 60 pounds per ton of kraft pulp, the major pulping
process in the United States.

Paper can be recycled to such uses as coarse paper, paper-
board, carton stock, roofing felt, and building board
without de-inking, i.e., without removing inks, binders,
coatings, and filters, thus producing less waste per ton
of pulp.  All reprocessing of papers is limited in the
number of cycles through which the basic cellulose fiber
can pass.  In the higher grades of paper, the loss per
cycle is 25 to 30 percent.  A maximum overall reuse rate
of 60% has been predicted, versus the current 20% in the
U. S. and 45% in tree-starved Japan.  Polychlorinated bi-
phenyls, an ingredient of some inks and carbonless repro-
duction paper until recently, is a very stable compound
which has been predicted to have adverse environmental
effects.  Materials such as this in much of the previously
                         116

-------
accumulated waste paper could be a  limiting factor in
reuse for, say, food containers.

Of major concern to the pulp and paper industry are the
effects on pollution abatement  costs in older plants and
in those whose operations  are marginally profitable.
Space problems are of  great concern in older plants.
Municipal co-treatment offers limited potential in most
pulp mills which are not near large cities; most plants
near municipal sewage  treatment facilities are very large
water users as compared to the  volume of sewage flows.

Correspondence with a  major non-ferrous metals company
indicates that their primary concern is that the costs
of pollution  abatement facilities be measured on the basis
of the  "opportunity costs" of capital.  This company's
concern is  largely with measures  such as "return on invest-
ment" or "return  on capital employed",  since they regard
themselves  as highly  capital  intensive.  The data on
Table  66 show some relationships  between investment, sales,
and  profitability for  8 major U.  S. Corporations.
                           117

-------
                      Table  66.   Comparative Tr.vest'-'d C.v-:ital ;-r.d Profitability
                                       Selectee: Industry Laadwrs
                                              Yo.ir 1171
Source:  Annual Reports
SECTION I - BASIC DATA

 Net Sales

 Cost of Goods Sold  (1)

 Invested Capital
  Net Worth  (Equity)
  Long-Term Debt and Notes,
   including amounts due
   within one year

     TOTAL

      N II
  Invested Capital/?  of Sales

SECTION  III

 A raarkup of  10%  on Cost of  Goods
   Sold  would  result  in a return
   on invested Capital  of ........

 A aarkup of  10*  on Invested
   Capital woul-J  result in a
   return on Cost of  Goods Sold of
(Amounts in Millions of Dollars)

                                                    Standard
                   General   General      Phelps-    Oil of      U.S.
   Alco-i  D'J Pont  Electric  Motors   IBM  Dodrre    Sew Jersey  Stoel
$1,441
1,328
1,269
976
2,245
$3
3
3

3
,848
,275
,095
236
,331
$ 9
8
2
1
4
,425
,683
,927
,357
,284
$28,
24,
10,

11,
264
608
805
616
421
$8,274
6,300
6,642
919
7,561
$704
632
710
166
8-76
$20
17
11
3
15
,362
,631
,593
,865
,453
$4,963
4,734
3,507
1,498
5,005
  $ l.r»S
                                                     .87   $   .45   $    .40 $   .91  $1.2-1    $   .76   S 1.01
    5.9%    9.8%
                                           16.94   10.24
                     20.3%     21.54   8.3%  7.2%
                                                              4.9J      4.6%  12.0% 13.9*
                                                       11.4%
                                                                 9.51
                                                                                                8.7%     10.6%
 (i)  Excludes  interest  where identified
                                            118
                                                               *U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE:1973  514-155/320  1-3

-------
SELECTED WATER
RESOURCES ABSTRACTS

INPUT TRANSACTION FORM
1. Rrjor? 'Vti.
                                                       2.
                    w
             ECONOMIC  FEASIBILITY OF MINIMUM INDUSTRIAL
         WASTE LOAD  DISCHARGE REQUIREMENTS
    <;*?•<•.!•'5)
         Bramer, Henry C.
         Datagraphics, Inc.
         5100  Centre Avenue, Pittsburgh, PA  15232
                    5.  RapvrtDate
                                                                  S. F- -torm;>,i, Orga.: Cation
                                                                    Report No.
                                                                    EPA-2800775
 12.  'Sr~"nsoriB* Organ.'  rtion
                       68-01-0196

                    13.  Typ>- .-fRep'-'ti
                       Period Coveted
 IS.  Su-,
         Environmental Protection Agency report number,
         EPA-R5-73-016, April 1973.
 ii:  *>•** »     This study presents order-of-magnitude estimates of the costs of imple-
 menting minimum and zero discharge  requirements  for the manufacturing and electric
 power industries.   The analysis was made,  for the most part, at the 2 digit S.I.C.
 level for the  manufacturing industries.  The assumed technology was maximum in-plant
 recirculation  and reuse, concentration of  the recirculation blowdown by evaporation,
 and final residual disposal by the  applicable least-cost method among incineration,
 deepwell disposal, solar evaporation, and  ocean  disposal.

              It is concluded that a  strict  zero discharge requirement would have
 greatly variable and significant economic  consequences, but that less stringent
 definitions  of minimum discharge would be  feasible.  The limiting factors in applying
 a strict zero  discharge requirement appear to be the availability of physical resources
 particularly energy, for purposes of effluent concentration.
   . Descriptors   *Economics, *Industrial  Wastes
 i"b. identifiers    *Treatment Costs
17c. CO WRR Field & Group  ^5D
                     •pfeVBMH

   Availability            J9:  Security Class.
                         "I. Sfc'-frity Cl' ;s.
                            (Page) •
                                           21. No. of
                                              Pages

                                           '2., Pit 9
         Send To:


         WATER RESOURCES SCIENTIFIC INFORMATION CENTER
         US DEPARTMENT OF THE INTERIOR
         WASHINGTON. D. C. ZO24O

-------