PB-202  353
A  MODEL  FOR  REGIONAL  AIR  POLLUTION  COST/BENE
FIT  ANALYSIS

Kenneth R.  Woodcock

TRW  Systems Group
McLean,  Virginia

May 1Q?1
       NATIONAL 'ECHNICAL INFORMATION SERVICE
                                               Distributed ... 'to foster, serve
                                                   and promote  the nation's
                                                      economic development
                                                          and technological
                                                            advancement.'
                            •
                          • •
                                                U.S. DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE
                This document has been approved lor public release and sale.

-------
                                              • •_ • ',4. '.''I'  ' -'.W  '•'.*
 Environmental Protection  Agency

rAir  Pollution Control Office

'Washington,  D.C.
•



 Contract  Mo.  PH  22-68-60
 •ft

-------
                        NOTICE



This document has been reproduced from the best copy



furnished us by the sponsoring agency.  Although it is



recognized that certain portions are illegible, it is



being released in the.interest  of making available as



much  information as possible.

-------
  STANDARD TITLE PAGE
  FOR TECHNICAL REPORTS
I. Report No.
  APTD-0708
3. Recipient's Catalog No.
 4. Title and SuotltM
 .A  Model for  Regional  Air Pollution Cost/Benefit
  Ann lys is
                                           S. Report Date
                                            May 1971
                                                              6. Performing Organization Code
 '. Authons)
  Kenneth R. Woodcock
                                           8. Performing Organization Kept. No.
 9. Performing Organization N«M and Address
  TRW  Systems  Group
  7600  Colshire  Drive
  McLean,  Virginia  22101

 TJVsponsoflng Agency Nan* and Addiwu"
  Environmental  Protection Agency
  Air  Pollution  Control  Office
  Research Triangle Park,  North  Carolina  27711
                                           10. ProJect/TasH/Work Unit No.

                                           TT. Cbmra57ffranrHeT

                                             PH 22-68-60

                                           13. Type of Report & Period Covered
                                                              14. Sponsoring A~ge~ncy~C3de
 13. supplementary note*
 16. Abstracts
 A description of  a cost/Benefit model  is presented.   This model  is an ex-
 tension  of the  Implementation planning Program,  a coat-effectiveness model
 which has  been  utilized  in  evaluating  regional emission  control  strategies
 for the  development of implementation  plans.   The specifications for the
 model for  sulfur  dioxide  and particulate pollutants have been  developed
 and are  presented.   The  report also  focuses  on:   -L. the  need for
 analytical procedures to  evaluate  the  economic consequences of air pol-
 lution control  strategies;   2-^ the  identification of  additional  research
 areas which need  consideration; $..»  a theoretical discussion of economic
 efficiency and  equity considerations of air  pollution  control  strategies;
 and 4. model utilization  in the air  pollution  control  decision-making
 process.
 17. Key Words and Document Analytli. (a). Descriptor*
 Atmosphere contamination  control
 Economic  analysis
 Economic  models
 Cost Benefit analysis
 Decision  theory
 Dus ts
 Aerosols
 Sulfur  dioxide
 17t>. identlflers/Open-Cnded Tpnw
 Implementation Planning
 Air Resource Management
 Air pollution  control
 Particulates
 17c. COSATI Field/Group    13 B ,  5C
        Program
 IB. Distribution Statement
                 Unlimited
                                 19. Security Class (This Report)
                                     UNCLASSIFIED
                                                    /O.Securlty Class. (This Page)
                                                        UNCLASSIFIED
                                                                       21. No. of Pages
                                                   22. Price
PONM NM-M741-70)

-------
                                 11130-W001-RO-00
A MODEL FOR REGIONAL AIR POLLUTION

      COST/BENEFIT ANALYSIS
       Kenneth R. Woodcock
             May 1971
           Prepared for
  Environmental Protection Agency
    Air Pollution Control Office
      Contract No. PH 22-68-60
         TRW SYSTEMS GROUP
        7600 Colshire Drive,
       McLean, Virginia 22101

-------
This report was furnished to the Offi.ce
of Air Programs by
   TRW Systems Group
   7600 Colshire Drive
   McLean, Virginia  22101
in fulfillment of Contract No. PH 22-68-60

-------
                            TABLE OF CONTENTS

                                                                     Page
1.0   EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ........... '. ...........      1
2.0   ECONOMIC ANALYSIS AND AIR RESOURCE PLANNING- ........     H
      2.1  AIR RESOURCE PLANNING—ECONOMIC DECISIONS .......     15
      2.2  APPLICATION OF ECONOMIC THEORY AND
           COST/BENEFIT ANALYSIS .............. • •  •  •     *-6
      2.3  USE OF THE REGIONAL AIR RESOURCE PLANNING MODEL ....
3.0   CURRENT AIR RESOURCE PLANNING PRACTICES ...........     19
      3.1  PHILOSOPHY OF AIR RESOURCE PLANNING. .. ........     20
      3.2  ESTABLISHED AIR RESOURCE DECISION-MAKING PROCEDURES .  .     22
           3.2.1  Nashville Metropolitan Area Air Resource
                  Management Plan ..... . • ..........     23
           3.2.2  Implementation Planning Under The
                  Clean Air Amendments of 1970 .....  .....     24
4.0   CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR REGIONAL AIR RESOURCE
      DECISION-MAKING. ........ ........... .........     31
      4.1  OVERVIEW ............ ............     31
      4.2  PROBLEMS IN AIR RESOURCE PLANNING ..... ........     34
      4.3  DECISION-MAKING OBJECTIVES. ...'.' .....  ' .....     37
      4.4  EVALUATION CRITERIA ....... . ..........     38
      4.5  APPLICATION OF COST/BENEFIT ANALYSIS TO AIR RESOURCE
           DECISION-MAKING .......... . .........     39
5.0   OVERVIEW OF THE COST/BENEFIT MODEL' ..... . .......     43
      5.1  VALUE OF THE COST/BENEFIT MODEL ............     45
      5'. 2  ALTERNATIVE TYPES OF MODELS . '. ........ ....     46
      5.3  COST/BENEFIT MODEL UTILIZATION  ...... .......     49
6.0   CONTROL COST ESTIMATING PROCEDURES ........... .  .     55
      6.1  IMPLEMENTATION PLANNING PROGRAM ...... .......     55
      6.2  POINT SOURCE CONTROL . COSTS . .... ..........     62
      6.3  AREA SOURCE CONTROL COSTS . . .............     62
      6.4  CONTROL AGENCY COSTS-  ... ....... ,  ......     63

-------
                       TABLE OF CONTENTS  (Continued)

                                                                     Page
7.0   BENEFIT MODEL ......... '. . , .............     67
      7.1  RECEPTOR DATA.  .....................     67
      7.2  DAMAGE FUNCTIONS .........  .....  ......     71
           7.2.1  Description of a Damage Function. ........     75
           7.2.2  Identification of Air Pollution Effects .....     78
           7.2.3  Assessment of Air Pollution Effects .......     82
           7.2.4  Evaluation of Air Pollution Effects .......     83
           7.2.5  Types of Air Pollution  Damage Functions ......     86
           7.2.6  Application of Air Pollution Damage Functions .  .     88
           7.2.7  Development of Damage Functions .........     95
8.0   SOME APPLICATIONS OF THE COST/BENEFIT MODEL .........     99
      .8.1  EMISSION CONTROL REGULATION DEVELOPMENT .  .  ......    999
      8.2  ANALYSIS OF THE DISTRIBUTION . ....  ..........    105
      8.3  PRACTICAL MODEL APPLICATION IN AQCRs ..........    109
      8.4  CRITERIA FOR EVALUATING STRATEGIES ...........    HO
      8.5  OTHER USES OF THE C/B MODEL .  .  ............    115
9.0   BIBLIOGRAPHY  ...........  .  .  ......  .....    117
      9.1  REGIONAL AIR QUALITY MANAGEMENT.  ............    117
      9.2  GENERAL COST/BENEFIT LITERATURE  ..........  .  .    H7
      9.3  THEORY AND APPLICATION OF COST/BENEFIT ANALYSIS.  ....    118
      9.4  RELEVANT AIR POLLUTION AND RELATED LITERATURE  .....    119
      9.5  SOCIAL INDICATORS  ...................
                               APPENDICES
A     THEORETICAL  CONSIDERATIONS OF AIR POLLUTION
      COST/BENEFIT ANALYSIS                                          123
B     PRACTICAL MEASURES FOR OBSERVATIONS OF COSTS
      AND BENEFITS                                                  141
C     EFFICIENCY EVALUATIONS OF COSTS AND BENEFITS                   149
D     CONTROL  SUPPLIER  FUNCTIONS                                     159
                                    iv

-------
                              ILLUSTRATIONS


Figure

1-1   Regional Air Pollution Cost/Benefit Model ..........

1-2   Direct Application of C/B Model in Strategy Analysis ....       6

1-3   Use of C/B Model with Economic Model System  .......  •       8

2-1   The Air Resource Loop  .....  ....  ..........      13

2-2   Air Pollution Efficiency Analysis  .......  •  .....      14

3-1   Scope of Air Quality Management  ..............      21

3-2   Roll-Back Technique  ........ " ............      25

3-3   The Testing of Emission Control Strategies  .........      27

3-4   Annual Arithmetic Mean Concentrations of  Suspended
      Particulate Pollutants as Estimated by Diffusion Model
      for Existing Conditions  .....  .............      28
3-5   Predicted Ground-Level Concentrations Following
      Application of Proposed Control Strategy •  •  •  •. ......      29

4-1   Air Resource Decision-Making Process ........  .....      32

4-2   The Path to Clean Air  ..........  •  ........      35
                                                               •
4-3   Flow of Costs and Benefits Over Time ............      36

4-4   The Concept of Air Pollution Cost/Benefit Analysis .....      41

5-1   Regional Air Pollution Cost/ Benefit Model .........  '•      44

5-2   Form of Regional Cross-Sectional Analysis ..........      47

5-3   Longitudinal Cost/Benefit Study of Air Quality  .......      48

5-4   Direct Application of C/B Model in Strategy Analysis  ....      50

5-5   Use of C/B Model with Economic Model System-  •  •  ......      52

5-6   Major Component of the Model ................      53

6-1   Implementation Planning Program ...............      56

6-2   Existing Ground Level Particulate Concentrations  in
      the NCIAQCR as Computed by the Verified Diffusion Model ...      59

-------
                       ILLUSTRATIONS (Continued)


Figure                                                               Page

6-3   Predicted Particulate Concentrations after
      the Enactment of the Proposed Emission
      Control Strategy in all Political Jurisdictions •  •  	     61

6-4   Accounting for Control Agency Costs 	     64

7-1   Benefit Model Design	     68

7-2   Crdss-Sectional Cost/Benefit Model for Given
      Pollutant and Damage Function 	     69

7-3 a  Receptor Points Superimposed on Census Tracts
      of the NCIAQCR  (Macroscopic view) 	     72

7-3b  Receptor Points Superimposed on Census Tracts
      of the NCIAQCR (Microscopic view)	     73

7-4   Receptor'Point - Census Tract Interface 	     74

7-5   Supply-Demand Relationship for Air Quality   	     76

7-6   What is a Damage Function?	     77

7-7   Damage Function - A Rate	     79

7-8   Structuring the Economic Effects of Air Pollution	     80

7-9   Social Benefits Resulting from Air Pollution Control.  ....     81

7-10  How to Value Air Pollution Effects?	     85

7-11  Example Damage Function for Direct Effects	     87

7-12  Example Damage Function for Market Effect  	     89

7-13  Application of Damage Functions 	     91

7-14  Historical Trends in Pollution Concentration	     93

7-15  Monthly Average Sulfur Dioxide Concentrations
      in the District of Columbia . .	     94

7-16  Comprehensive Damage Function for an AQCR	• •     96

8-1   Existing Ground Level Particulate Concentrations
      in the NCIAQCR as Computed by the Verified  Diffusion Model- .    101
                                   vi

-------
                       ILLUSTRATIONS (Continued)


Figure                                                               Page

8-2   Predicted Particulate Concentrations after
      Enactment of the Proposed Emission Control
      Strategy in all Polutical Jurisdictions (Strategy 18)....    102

8-3   Predicted Air Quality Improvement in the NCIAQCR 	    103

8-4   Source Equity vs. Receptor Equity	    104
                                       •

8-5   Source Equity (Position A) 	    104

8-6   Source Equity (Position B) 	    106

8-7   An Emission Standard Based on Geographical Location	    107

8-8   Use of the Cost/Benefit Model in an AQCR	    Ill

A-l   Classification of Direct Effects 	    125

A-2   Identification of Adjustments	    126

A-3   Structuring the Economic Effects of Air Pollution	    127

A-4   Cost of Control and Cost of Pollution	    132

A-5   Cost of Control and Benefits	    133

A-6   Pareto-Relevant and Pareto-Irrelevant Externalities	    135

A-7   Internalization of the Cost of Pollution	    136.

A-8   Relevant Costs of Air Pollution Disposal  . '	    137

A-9   Reduction of the Relevant Costs of Air
      Pollutant Disposal 	    139

B-l   Point Source Control Cost vs. Total Regiq^al
      Particulate Emission Rate for NCIAQCR 	 for
      Selected Strategies	    143

B-2   Point Source Marginal Control Cost vs.  Total
      Regional Particulate Emission Rate for NCIAQCR
      	for Selected Strategies	    145

B-3   Point Source Control Costs vs.  Total Regional
      Sulfur Oxide Emission Rate for NCIAQCR 	 for
      Selected Strategies	    146

B-4   Point Source Marginal Control Cost vs.  Total Regional
      Sulfur Dioxide Emission Rate for NCIAQCR 	 for
      Selected Strategies. .  	    147
                                   vii

-------
                                TABLES
                                                                     Page

6-1   Implementation Planning Program. ...... ...........     60

7-1   Regression Results of Anderson-Crocker
      Study for the Washington, D.  C., SMSA ............     90

7-2   Example Data for the Development of
      Damage Functions for Heal Effects*  •  ............     97
B-l   Selected Control Strategies for the NCIAQCR-  •  .......     144
                                  viii

-------
                          1.0  EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

     The Cost/Benefit Model described in this report is an extension of
the Implementation Planning Program (IPP), a cost-effectiveness model
which has been utilized in evaluating regional emission control strategies
for the development of implementation plans.  The specifications for the
Model for sulfur dioxide and particulate pollutants have been developed
over the past six months and are presented in this report.  As a follow-on
to this effort, the Cost/Benefit Model is now being developed and demon-
strated in the National Capital Interstate Air Quality Control Region.
The users' manual and demonstration results o'f the Model will be available
by June 1971.
     This report goes beyond the presentation of the Model specifications
and also focuses on:  (1)  the need for analytical procedures to evaluate
the economic consequences of air pollution control strategies; (2) the
identification of additional research areas which need consideration; (3)
a theoretical discussion of economic efficiency and equity considerations
of air pollution control strategies; and (A) Model utilization in the air
pollution control decision-making process.
     The air pollution problem in the United States is now approached
through a complex series of policies.   The Nation is attempting to repair
the damages caused by negative externalities from our expanding economy.
Public pressures are forcing the development of rapid solutions.  Air
quality standards have been established on the basis of the best available
information in the world.  Nonetheless, the standard setting procedure is
not based on comprehensive studies or complete data.  It is possible that
today's standards will  be modified and improved as better decision-making
information becomes available..
     Unfortunately, regional air resource policies are being established
without the required sensitivity to economic conditions.  Since economic
considerations are not included, the potential impact of these policies
on the regional and national economy has not been evaluated.  Analytical
tools are needed to inform decision-makers of the economic consequences
of air resource policies.  Tools are needed to evaluate the economic
efficiency and equity aspects of the impact of air pollution control

-------
policies on sources and receptors.   Tools for evaluating strategies must
be designed which will be compatible with the regional decision-making
process and with regional environmental and urban-planning goals and
objectives.  There is clearly a need for a broader analytical approach,
which includes the examination of long-term land-use plans and plans for
regional economic growth.
     At the present,  the only analytical tools available for the develop-
ment of regional emission control strategies are the "rollback technique"
and the cost-effectiveness analysis approach of IPP.  The "rollback tech-
nique" is  used to estimate the required regional emission reduction but
does not examine the  spatial distribution of pollution concentrations
within an  air quality control region  (AQCR).  IPP predicts pollution con-
centrations at numerous geographical  locations in an AQCR and predicts
control costs for the major point sources.  Yet, the procedure for deter-
mining the effectiveness of control strategies merely evaluates the
difference between the predicted pollution  concentration and the air
quality standard.  Considerations of  regional and national economic impact
are not directly included in the analysis..
     This  report outlines a basic framework for analytical procedures that
may assist the air quality and emission standard-setting process, which
has been used as a guide in the development of the Cost/Benefit Model.
The Model  represents an initial attempt to  integrate economic, cost/benefit,
and systems analysis into air pollution control decision-making.
     The Cost/Benefit Model and it's  relationship to IPP is illustrated in
Figure 1-1.  The major outputs of IPP used  in the Cost/Benefit Model are
the point  source-control costs and the air quality display.  The point
source control costs are currently the only available measure of the social
cost of air pollution control in the Model.  Procedures for predicting area
source control costs and control agency costs are described in this report
but have,   thus far, not been included in the Model.
     The major portion of this study  is devoted to the development of the
                       I
Benefit Model (see Figure 1-1) which  relates the predicted pollution con-
centration (i.e., air quality display) to receptor data and damage func-
tions.  The exposure of receptors to pollutants (a measure of dosage) is

-------
n
INPUTS
   IMPLEMENTATION PLANNING PROGRAM
  • AIR QUALITY
    DATA	
 METEOROLOG-
 ICAL DATA	
  • EMISSION
    INVENTORY—I
  • CONTROL
    TECHNIQUES
    AND COSTS
ATMOSPHERIC
DIFFUSION
MODEL
                                           CALIBRATION
                                           PROCEDURE
I	

IES
rs
1
-+

CONTROL
COST FILE


-k rr
                                           EXISTING
                                           AIR
                                           QUALITY
                                           DISPLAY
                                  CONTROL
                                  STRATEGY
                                  MODEL
                         AJR
                         QUALITY
                         DISPLAY
               I          v uri./-* i
  • RECEPTOR
    DATA	
   DAMAGE
   FUNCTIONS

                      BENEFIT
                      MODEL
                                           1
                                          POINT
                                          SOURCE
                                          CONTROL
                                          COSTS
               AREA
               SOURCE
               CONTROL
               COSTS
                                  CONTROL
                                  STRATEGIES
                                      I
                                                    CONTROL
                                                    AGENCY
                                                    COSTS
        Figure 1-1.  Regional Air Pollution Cost/Benefit Model

-------
determined by the air quality-receptor relationship.   The damage function
(which relates the annual cost of air pollution damage to pollution con-
centration) when applied to the dosage estimate, determines the damage
cost estimate desired.  Estimates of benefits (i.e.,  a reduction in damages)
are calculated by subtracting damage estimates for alternative strategies
from the damages caused by existing atmospheric conditions.
     Three categores of economic effects from air pollution can be evalua-
ted  with the Benefit Model.  These are:  (1) direct  effects; (2) adjust-
ments (or indirect effects); and (3) induced  effects.  Direct  effects  are
immediate negative externalities borne by the receptor.  'Indirect effects
are those which induce persons or firms to make certain adjustments in
order to  reduce  the direct  impact of pollutants.  Induced  effects are
realized  through  the  marketplace as a  result of adjustments made.
     The greatest deficiencies in the proposed analytical procedures are
caused by the lack of acceptable damage functions.  Damage functions relate
one's "willingness-to-pay" to avoid air pollution (i.e., the social value
of cleaning up the atmosphere) to the pollution concentration to which a
person or thing is exposed.  Such relationships are extremely difficult to
develop.  Documented results are just now appearing on the Horizon.
     Even without damage functions, the Cost/Benefit  Model can be used for
"exposure" studies since knowledge of the relationship between pollution
concentration and receptors (for alternative emission control strategies)
is by itself valuable for decision-making.  As damage functions are de-
veloped, they will play a greater role in the analysis.   This report
includes a discussion about the problems of damage function development
and the application.  The steps involved in developing damage functions
include the identification, assessment, and evaluation of air pollution
                               •
damages.  The evaluation procedure is based on the economic concept of
"shadow pricing."
     Comprehensive evaluations of all costs and benefits of air pollution
control strategies are not possible with the Cost/Benefit Model.  The
Model merely accounts for a part of the control costs and a part of the
benefits.  It should be understood that the results to be obtained from
the Model demonstration will be considered tentative.

-------
     Such a model is possible at this time because economic research on
air pollution is beginning to provide control cost estimates for individ-
ual plants, industries, and the nation.  Such control cost estimates are
annually reported in the Economics of Clean Air Report.  Also, there is
increased awareness of the economic effects of air pollution on health,
materials, vegetation, soiling, esthetics, and residential property values.
A major task for the future is the transformation of the economic data in-
to the damage function form.
     This report proposes that the Cost/Benefit Model be used in two sepa-
rate ways.  First, the Model can be used in intensive welfare economic
studies of regional air pollution control strategies to provide a measure
of the cost and benefits of control strategies and changes in the well-
being of receptors in the region.  Control costs and benefits are used
directly in evaluating the economic efficiency and equity consideration
of control strategies.  Actual changes in well-being (i.e., welfare) can
be compared with the desired changes (that is, compared to the goals or
objectives of the regional decision-makers).  The Model can be used to
evaluate air quality standards, land-use plans, industrial development
siting, and other regional plans.  In this use, the Cost/Benefit Model is
especially valuable in considering the impacts of control strategies on
sources and receptors in different locations in the region.  Figure 1-2
illustrates the use of the Model for this purpose.
     This type of analysis, however, is limited in scope.  The second
proposed application of the Model is to provide data which can be used to
estimate impacts of control costs and benefits on the economic activity
of the region or the nation.  Air pollution control policies stimulate a
reallocation of resources which are reflected as changes in economic indi-
cators.  The Cost/Benefit Model does not include an analysis of such eco-
nomic indicators.  Policy analysis should include the identification of
changes in employment, capital investment, regional income, value added,
and other measures of economic activity.
     To measure changes in regional and national economic activity, control
costs and benefit estimates from the Cost/Benefit Model will serve as in-
puts to an economic model system developed as part of this contract by

-------
                                                            AIR QUALITY.
                                                            DATA
                                                            METEOROLOG-
                                                            ICAL DATA
                                                                                                                           i.
-k
*-

ATMOSPHERIC
DIFFUSION
MODEL


CALIBRATION
PROCEDURE
1
STATEMENT OF
AN ALTERNATIVE
SOLUTION, (IE,
EMISSION CON-
TROL STRATEGY)

INVtNIUKT. | ^
• TECHNIQUES
AND COSTS
CONTROL
COST FILE




i
CONTROL
STRATEGY
MODEL .
AIRQU
DISPLA1
, 	 1
1
                                                                                                                        POINT
                                                                                                                        SOURCE
                                                                                                                        CONTROL
                                                                                                                        COSTS
                      DECISION
                       MAKER
                                                 KNOWLEDGE OF
                                             IDENTIFIABLE EFFECTS (IE, COSTS AND BENEFITS) NOT
                                                                                                         AIR QUALITY
                                                                                                         DISPLAY
                                   ADEQUATELY MEASUREA8LE FOR THE FUNCTIONAL FORM
                                                                                                             AREA
                                                                                                             SOURCE
                                                                                                             CONTROL
                                                                                                             COSTS
                                                    TANGIBLE
                                                    EFFECTS
PLAN OBJECTIVES
                                                                                                                        REGIONAL
                                                                                                                        CONTROL
                                                                                                                         COSTS
                                                                                 DIRECT EFFECTS
                                                                                 ADJUSTMENTS
                                                                                 MARKET EFFECTS
                                                        SHADOW PRICES
                                                                                                  f REGIONAL}
                                                                                                  I BENEFITS I
                                         ANALYSIS
                                         OF GOALS
BROAD
BASED
OBJECTIVES
INTERMEDIATE
OBJECTIVES
NARROW
OBJECTIVES
                Figure 1-2.   Direct  Application of C/B  Model in StVategy  Analysis

-------
CONSAD Research Corporation.  The economic model system currently consists
of two major components, namely, a regional economic model (which has been
applied to 100 air quality control regions) and a national input/output
mode.  The regional economic model determines the economic effects of air
pollution control costs and benefits flowing from the control strategies
pursued in a region.  The national input/output model system is introduced
to provide external markets (i.e., provide feedback effects between that
region and all other regions) for the regional economy, and also to mea-
sure the structural changes in the national economy following the applica-
tion of air pollution control regulations to the 100 AQCRs.  An illustra-
tion of the Cost/Benefit Model as used with the economic model system is
presented in Figure 1-3.
     The Cost/Benefit Model is a cross-sectional model, i.e., air pollution
control policies can be evaluated at one point in time.  Conventional cost/
benefit analyses require that costs and benefits be traced over a predeter-
mined period of time.  Costs and benefits are then discounted back to the
current year before the marginal costs and benefits of policies are evalua-
ted.   The current CONSAD economic model system is also cross-sectional.
Longitudinal cost/benefit and other economic studies will be possible if
and when a time series national economic model is incorporated into the
CONSAD economic model system.
     The overall objectives of this study have been accomplished through
the following:
          1.  Investigating the theoretical literature on
              cost/benefit, analysis and research reports
              on the application of cost/benefit analysis
              to public investment projects and social
              programs.
          2.  Examining the need for more advanced analytical
              procedures to support the air resource decision-
              making process.
          3.  Developing a conceptual design for incorporating
              analytical procedures into the decision-making
              process, including the techniques of systems
              analysis, cost/benefit analysis, and economic
              analysis.

-------
           • AIR QUALITY
             DATA      "
           • METEOROLOG-
             ICAL DATA
i EMISSION
 INVENTORY*

i CONTROL
 TECHNIQUES
 AND COSTS
                              IMPLEMENTATION PLANNING PROGRAM
                                        (TRW SYSTEMS)



ATMOSPHERIC
DIFFUSION
MODEL


CALIBRATION
PROCEDURE
1
                                CONTROL
                                COST FILE
               EXISTING
               AIR QUALITY
               DISPLAY
CONTROL
STRATEGY
MODU
« 1


00
       -
                              • DAMAGE
                               FUNCTIONS
                               . DIRECT EFFECTS
                               • ADJUSTMENTS
                               • MARKET EFFECTS
                  COST/BENEFIT MODEL
             (PARTIALLY UNDER DEVELOPMENT)
                 POINT
                 SOURCE
                 CONTROL
V      \         COST

        AREA
        SOURCE
        CONTROL
        COSTS
   • CONTROL
    AGENCY
    COSTS
                                                fREGIONALt
                                                  BENEFITS
                         ECONOMIC MODEL SYSTEM
                         (CONSAD RESEARCH CORP)
                                                                                          REGIONAL VARIABLES
                                                                                          AT PREVIOUS YEAR:
                                                                                           VALUE ADDED
                                                                                           CAPITAL STOCK
                                                                                           CONSUMPTION
                                                                                           REGIONAL INCOME
                                                                                           POPULATION AND
                                                                                           MIGRATION
                                                                                            GOVERNMENT
                                                                                            EXPENDITURE
REGIONAL INDUSTRIAL
INVESTMENT RE-
QUIRED BY AIR
POLLUTION ABATEMENT
STRATEGY
                               NATIONAL
                               INPUT/OUTPUT
                               MODEL
                                     ECONOMIC GAINS
                                     OF AIR POLLUTION
                                     CONTROL
                                                                                                            REGIONAL
                                                                                                            ECONOMETRIC
                                                                                                            MODEL
                                                                                         REGIONAL INCOME
                                                                                         AND CONSUMPTION
                                                                                                                                    I NOUS I RIAL
                                                                                                                                     OUTPUT
                                                                                                                                     INVESTMENT
                                                                                                                                     EMPLOYMENT
                                                                                                                                     CAPITAL STOCK
                                                      REGIONAL
                                                       UNEMPLOYMENT
                                                       LABOR FORCE
CHANGES Of REGIONAL
INCOME. CONSUMP-
TION, VALUE ADDED.
INVESTMENT AND EM-
PLOYMENT 8Y INDUS-
TRY, REGIONAL UNEM-
PLOYMENI GENIRAICD
»Y DIRECT COSTS  AND
BENEFITS OF EACH
ABATEMENT STRATEGY
                                             Figure  1-3.   Use of  C/B Model  with Economic Model  System

-------
          A.  Preparing specifications for the development
              of a Benefit Model and other procedures which
              facilitate comprehensive evaluations of air
              resource policies.

          5.  Collecting data  (i.e., census data, damage
              functions, etc.) and preparing a "pilot"
              Benefit Model for examining the feasibility
              of the approach.

          6.  Testing the use of census data in the present
              IPP design.

          1.  Identifying the types of analyses which will
              best utilize the capabilities of the Cost/
              Benefit Model.  This includes;
                                        «.
              -  examining economic efficiency and
                 equity considerations of emission
                 control strategies, and

              -  examining new ways of developing
                 regional emission standards.

     Much additional work is required before a comprehensive, reliable
model can be developed.  This report identifies many of the gaps and
deficiencies in the current version of the Model.  Potential research
areas have been identified to facilitate the evolution of analytical
procedures for rational regional air pollution analyses.  Some of the
                                                              •
gap areas (and location in this text where the subject is treated) are:

          •   Damage functions  (Section 7.2)

          •   Control supplier functions (Appendix D)
          •   Area source control cost functions (Section 6.3)
          •   Upgraded point source control costs (Section 6.2)
          •   Control agency costs (Section 6.4)

          •   Economic, social and impact indicators (Section 8.4)
          •   Regional decision-making framework,
              including,

                 - evaluation criteria (Section 4.4)
                 - regional objectives (Section 4.3)

-------
      Modeling and comprehensive analyses are likely to play an increasingly
 significant role in APCO activities.  As the framework for comprehensive
 analyses is developed, it will serve as a guide for identification of the
 types of research and monitoring data that should be provided by Federal,
 State, and local air pollution control activities.   The full value of re-
 search and surveillance data can only be realized through integrated ana-
 lytical procedures designed to serve the "decision-making process.   Such
 procedures must be sensitive to quantitative and qualitative inputs from
 all professional disciplines which contribute to the problem solving pro-
 cess.  The procedures must allbw use1of available data for current
 decision-making, and should also help in identifying data needed for the
 evaluation of policies aimed at meeting long-range goals.
      This report leaves many gaps and unanswered questions.  Hopefully,
• other researchers will evaluate this work and develop further procedures •
       w •
 for analyzing the problem.
                                      10

-------
             2.0  ECONOMIC ANALYSIS AND AIR RESOURCE PLANNING

      The U. S. economy is now undergoing a shift in orientation, from an
approach in which emphasis was placed upon the satisfaction of human wants
without regard to environmental effects toward a sensitivity to the preser-
vation of natural resources.  Laws enacted to stimulate and protect the
economic institutions which supply goods and services to our citizens have
proved inadequate to maintain the quality of life, and externalities from
our productive economy have begun to infringe upon the utility of the
economy output itself.  Legislation is now being rapidly enacted in an
attempt to repair past damage.  If rational Judgments are made, a state
of equilibrium will some day be reached in which the undesirable side
effects of production and consumption will be minimal.  In this connection,
the present report examines the air resource decision-making process and
provides an introduction to the development of a tool which will aid
policy-makers in better determining the condition for the air resource.
      The Air Quality Act of 1967 laid a framework for air resource deci-
             *
sions at the regional level.  The Act provided for the establishment of
air quality control regions, utilization of air quality criteria and con-
trol technology documents to set standards, and preparation of implementa-
tion plans for attaining these standards.
      The Clean Air Amendments of 1970 modified the procedures by, among
other things, establishing primary and secondary air quality standards.
The entire nation was divided into a number of air quality control regions.
A time schedule was determined for the development of implementation plans
by the regions.  Also, procedures were proposed for determining the ade-
quacy of implementation plans in attaining air quality standards.
      Additional tools and procedures are needed, however, if the air
quality control regions are to properly evaluate their air resource prob-
lems and the regional impact which will result from alternative policies.
Since knowledge of the total effects of atmospheric pollution and the
precise economic relevancy of air resource policies to sources within a
region is inadequate, decisions are being based primarily upon political
considerations and limited amounts of scientific evidence and economic
data.   Improved  decisions will be  possible as more scientific  evidence

                                    11

-------
becomes available.  Kor now, decisions must press forward toward advance-
ment in pollution control.
      Unfortunately, regional air resource policies are now being estab-
lished without the required sensitivity to .economic conditions.  The air
resource and the regional economy are interconnected, as shown in Figure
2-1.  Regional policies are being established on the basis of an examina-
tion of pollution sources and related control technologies, specific
pollutants and emission rates, ambient air quality in the region, and
effects of air quality on the receptors.  Since economic considerations are
not included, potential impact on the regional and national economy has not
been evaluated.  Nonetheless, such effects as changes in fuel prices,
added production costs, and increased cost of electrical power may influence
such areas as unemployment, inflation, and the balance of payments.  These
factors must be examined.
      From the standpoint of economics, efficiency considerations in rela-
tion to the air pollution problem may be portrayed as shown in Figure 2-2.
After all relevant tangible and intangible effects are considered, primary
concern is directed to the marginal cost of control and the marginal bene-
fits (that is, the marginal reduction in air pollution damages), which are
functions of regional pollution concentration.  The goal of the decision-
maker is to attain a level of pollution concentration where society's
welfare is maximized.  This conditions exists at the intersection of the
marginal cost and marginal benefit curves in Figure 2-2.
      In the political debate over desirable levels of air quality, it was
argued that a moralistic approach to the problem does not lend itself to
rational solutions.1  Decision-makers have likewise been cautioned against
proposing overly strict (i.e. , uneconomical) solutions to the regional
problem:  "Recently air pollution control has become a major field for the
practice of this art of one-upmanship by many of our political leaders."2
Overly strict control may be uneconomical.
1
 Henry Ford II, Washington Post, p. A16, November 23, 1970,
2
 D. A. Jenson, APCA Journal, p. 643, October 1970.
                                    12

-------
                      AIR RESOURCE
POLLUTANTS
                    CURRENT POLICY
                    BASED ON KNOWLEDGE
                    OF THESE CRITERIA
AIR QUALITY
 SOURCES
     1
 RECEPTORS
                         REGIONAL
                         ECONOMY
                                                         AN ECONOMIC EVALUATION DEFINES
                                                         OBJECTIVES AND MEASURES IMPACT
                                                         IN TERMS OF REGIONAL WELFARE
                         NATIONAL
                         ECONOMY
                    Figure 2-1.  The Air Resource Loop

-------
E
en
IS)
1/1
o
a:
CO


g

»—I

C£
      MARGINAL
      CONTROL
      COST
                                              MARGINAL
                                              BENEFITS
                                                 POLLUTION
                                                 CONCENTRATION
          Figure 2-2.  Air Pollution  Efficiency Analysis

-------
      On the other hand, the use of effects criteria for setting standards
may result in a plan which is not sufficiently stringent.  If effects data
are not integrated into the decision-making process, proposed emission
standards will not adequately prevent the observed negative externalities
and new standards will soon be required.   Such changes in standards repre-
sent a costly process.  Analytical tools  are needed which will inform the
decision-maker of the economic consequences of air resource policies.  Such
tools, will be useful now and of even greater value in the future, when air
resources reach essentially steady-state  conditions.  At that time, changes
within the regional economy (e.g., a major new pollution source, new pro-
ducts, or other innovations) will require intensive evaluation to determine
their environmental impact.  More formal  and rigorous economic evaluations
                                          •.
of air resource policies are necessary, for both present and future
applications.
2.1  AIR RESOURCE PLANNING—ECONOMIC DECISIONS
      Air resource management decisions can be made without the aid of
"economics."  Air quality improvements have been justified on the basis
of such criteria as the satisfaction or dissatisfaction of those affected,
scientific analysis of air pollution damage, etc.  Economics merely at-
tempts to place a value (i.e., a price) on the phenomena which cause or
are affected by a polluted air resource.   As the "science of choice,"
economics can be used in the decision-making process to reduce all effects
of a policy to a common denominator (a common monetary unit).  Even where
all relevant values cannot be quantified, the "economic approach often
provides a useful way of thinking about the problems and a useful way of
organizing data for decision-makers."1
      To analyze the economic aspects of the problem appropriate economic
tools are required.  In this report, welfare economics is applied in the
form of a cost/benefit  (C/B) a'nalysis as a means of evaluating social
well-being within a region.  The procedures for air pollution C/B analysis
are not unlike those used in other public investment decision, including
 l
 A. V. Kneese, and B. T. Bower, Managing Water Quality:  Economics,
 Technology, Institutions, John Hopkins Press, Baltimore, Md., p. 8, 1968.
                                     15

-------
water resource analysis, although measurement of the extremely subtle
effects of air pollution greatly complicates the analysis.  The material
presented here represents a step toward a comprehensive, systematic,
and logical approach to the quantitative and qualitative evaluation of
air resource plans.
2.2  APPLICATION OF ECONOMIC THEORY AND COST/BENEFIT ANALYSIS
      Cost/Benefit analysis may be effectively applied in determining the
optimum allocation of resources for a public project or program.  Such an .
application is analogous to the use of financial or investment analysis by
the private sector to evaluate corporate or private ownership investment
projects.  The analytical problem in the private sector is much less com-
plex since market prices are available by which to measure the flow of
costs and benefits over time.  In the public sector, governments invest
funds and make decisions where the forces of supply and demand break down
(that is, where the economy alone does not provide the degree of well-being
desired by the society).  There is no marketplace where the externalities
created by emission sources are corrected by the inherent demand of the
receptors for clean air.  When regional governments attempt to solve the
                                                           t
problem, they are forced to consider causes and effects outside the market-
place and are left with no means for readily evaluating the costs and bene-
fits of an investment decision or public program.  C/B analysis of public
programs is thus complicated by problems associated with both the measure-
ment and the evaluation of effects.
      Cost/Benefit analysis has long been used to evaluate public programs.
Prest and Turvey1 trace the development of C/B analysis from 1844, the year
in which Dupuit's classic study on the utility of public works appeared in
France.  Dupuit's treatise represented a highly significant breakthrough in
economics.  Cost/Benefit analysis first achieved prominence in the United
States, however, where it was found to be particuaarly applicable to naviga-
tion problems.  The River and Harbor Act of 1902 required a board of engi-
neers to report on the desirability of river and harbor projects under
 A, R. Prest, and R. Turvey, "Cost-Benefit Analysis:  A Survey, "The
Economic Journal, vol. 75, No. 300, p. 683, December 1965.

                                    16

-------
consideration by the Army Corps of Engineers, taking into account the
benefits to commerce and the cost.  Under the New Deal in the 1930's, the
idea of a broader social justification for projects developed.  The Flood
Control Act of 1936 authorized Federal participation in flood control
schemes "if the benefits to whomsoever they may accrue are in excess of
the estimated cost."  Other agencies soon accepted the concept of C/B
analysis, and in 1950 an interagency committee produced the "Green Book,"
which attempted to codify and agree on general analytical principles. • C/B
analysis flourished in the 1960's, initially through Department of Defense
acceptance of the planning-programming-budgeting (PPB) system and later as
a result of President Johnson's desire that this tool be utilized through-
out the government.  It is now being applied to numerous socially oriented
programs in such areas as urban renewal, transportation, and health.
2.3  USE OF THE REGIONAL AIR RESOURCE PLANNING MODEL
      The analytical structure presented in this report combines systems
analysis and C/B analysis to provide a formal structuring of causes and
            i
effects associated with the air pollution control problem.  Such a frame-
work provides a means for maximizing the utility of research findings and
drawing attention to parameters not previously considered in the decision-
making process.  The approach can be used to identify future research
needs and to prevent misallocation of resources.   Finally, a computerized
tool for C/B analysis offers opportunities to gain further knowledge by
examining the interrelationships between relevant factors through trial
and error or through sensitivity analysis.
      In defining present and future environmental requirements, the
Council on Environmental Quality (CEQ)  recently stated:  "The pressing
need for tomorrow is to know much more than we do today.  We lack scienti--
fic data about how natural forces work on our environment and how pollutants
alter our natural world.   We lack experience in innovating solutions.   We
lack tools to tell us whether our environment is  improving or deteriorating.
And most of  all,  we lack an agreed-upon basic concept from which to look at
environmental problems and then to solve them"1
 II. S.  Council on Environmental Quality, Environmental Quality (First Annual
Report),  U.  S. Government Printing Office, Washington, D.  C.,p.  231,  1970.
                                    17

-------
Specifically, Che need was expressed for:  (1)  a conceptual framework,
(2) stronger institutions, (3) financial reform, (4) pollution control
curb, (5) monitoring and research, (6) a system of priorities, and (7)
comprehensive policies.*
      A system directed toward the systematic evaluation of air pollution
control strategies is proposed here.  The proposed system can be used in
the structuring and planning of such programs to ensure that the results
of monitoring and research efforts are utilized to the maximum extent in
the decision-making process.
1
 Ibid., pp. 232-239.
                                    18

-------
              3.0  CURRENT AIR RESOURCE PLANNING PRACTICES


      In this chapter, existing air resource planning practices are briefly

reviewed in order to place the proposed air resource decision-making and

simulation tools in proper perspective.  The proposed decision-making

process builds upon air resource management procedures which have evolved

over the past 20 years.  Topics covered in this review include the need
                                       •
for regulations, the philosophy of air resource management,  and air re-

source planning practices.

      The need for air pollution regulations is vividly expressed in the

following passage by Otto A.  Davis and Morton I.  Kamien:
                                                                 •
            Imagine for the sake of argument that the -auto industry had
            developed an effective smog control device which it offered
            as optional equipment for all new cars.   A person who was
            considering whether or not to order this optional for his new
            car might reason as follows:  Suppose I  purchase the smog con-
            trol devices for my new car.  If I purchase and  everyone else
            also purchases, then we will have less smog in the city.   On
            the other hand, my individual car can add only a negligible
            amount to the smog problem so that if everyone else purchases
            a device and I do not do so, then the smog will  be diminished
            by almost exactly the same amount and I  will  have saved the
            cost of the device.  Hence, if everyone  else  purchases  a
            device, I will be better off if I do  not get  one installed on
            my car.  Now presume that no one, with the possible exception
            of myself, purchases a device.   Obviously, there will be a
            6mog problem.   However, if I purchase a  device the problem
            will not be noticeably different, since  my individual car con-
            tributes only negligibly to the situation and I  will be out of
            the money which I paid for the smog control device.   Hence,
            if no one else purchases, I should not purchase  either.   Ob-
            viously, the analysis is the same if  some of  the other  people
            purchase and some do not.  Conclusion:   I will be better off,
            no matter what other people do,  if I  do  not purchase a  smog
            control device.

            Since all potential new car buyers will  reason roughly  as the
            representative individual above,  the  result is that there will
            be a zero demand for smog control devices.  Hence,  in the
            absence of some kind of regulation or collective decision,
            the automobile manufacturers will have no motivation to develop
            and market smog control devices.   This conclusion holds even
            if—and it is  an  if—everyone would be better off if all cars
            were equipped with smog control  devices.   The point is  that
            for each prospective purchaser of a device, the  benefits from
                                    19

-------
            his purchase are widely dispersed while the costs accrue to
            him.  Thus the technological externality associated with the
            exhaust of a car prevent the unregulated market from
            leading the system to a Pareto optimum.1
3.1  PHILOSOPHY OF AIR RESOURCE PLANNING
      A distinction is made in this report between air resource planning
and air quality management in order to differentiate between the analyti-
cal studies which evaluate the desired characteristics of an air resource,
including impact on the economy, and the broader responsibilities in the
field of air quality management, which include development of dn.air re-
source policy as well as operation of a pollution control agency (see
Figure 3-1).  Air resource planning involves the development and analysis
of air resource policies.  Air qualtiy management involves the implementa-
tion and critical review of such a policy.  The present report focuses on
the problem of developing air resource policies and omits consideration of
administrative procedures.
      In discussing the air resource management concept, Schueneman notes
that ' little or no consideration has been given to long-range planning,
or how proposed community or regional master plans might influence future
                     2
ambient air quality."   He states that an air resource management program
"must provide for the assimilation of information into goals and policies,
and the subsequent enunciation of a public policy on the management of the
                          o
community's air resource."   Essential elements of an air resource manage-
ment program are as follows:
            1.   Development of a public policy on air conservation.
            2.   An organizational framework and staff capable of operating
                along functional lines (e.g., engineering, technical
                services, field services)  and the funding support.
 U, S. Congress, Joint Economic Committee, The Analysis and Evaluation of
 Public Expenditures:  The PPB System, U. S. Government Printing Office,
 Washington, D. C., Vol. I, p. 76, 1969.
 J. Schueneman, "Air Pollution Control Administration," in Air Pollution,
 A, Stem, ed., (2nd Ed.), Vol. Ill, p. 721, 1968.
3Ibid., p. 722.
                                    20

-------
AIR
RESOURCE
PLANNING
                      AIR RESOURCE
                      DECISION-MAKER
AIR
RESOURCE
POLICY




TECHNICAL


•ENGINEERING
STUDIES




ENFORCEMENT


•REGULATIONS (I.E.




SURVEILLANCE


, «AIR MONITORING




ADMINISTRATIVE


•PERSONNEL


EPISODE
PREVENTION
PLANNING
•EPISODE CRITERI
INDUCEMENTS)
•METEOROLOGICAL
• EFFECTS STUDIES
• ANALYSIS
•LEGAL AUTHORITY
.•COMPLIANCE
• RESOURCES
MONITORING
• FIELD INSPECTION
•COMMUNITY
RAPPORT
•EMERGENCY ACTIO
PLAN

• EPISODE
nDfcANT7ATinN
                      •DATA HANDLING

                     ••SOURCE TESTING
         Figure 3-1.  Scope of Air Quality Management

-------
            3.  Delineation of realistic short-range goals that can be
                effectively met in a reasonable time period, say 5 years.

            4.  Continual assessment of existing air quality and prepara-
                tion of estimates of the.future situation.

            5.  Assessment in depth, on a continuing basis, of the emissions
                from all existing pollution sources and those expected to
                exist in the future.

            6.  Development of the necessary information about factors
                that influence the transport of air pollutants.

            7.  Assessment of the effects of ambient air quality of a
                community or region on man and his environment.

            8.  Establishment of ambient air quality goals (referred to
                by some as objectives or standards).

            9.  Design of remedial measures and programs calculated to
                bring about the air quality desired.

           10.  Development of long-range air use plans, fully integrated
                with other community plans for energy supplies, land use,
               • transportation, recreation, refuse disposal, etc., to
                cope effectively with changes projected for the community.

           11.  Development of an understanding of the broad 'impact of
                changing science and technology on air resources and the
                potential effect on the social and economic character of
                modern society.

           12.  Development of an effective information and educational
                program to inform the community of the need to solve air
                pollution problems promptly and effectively.

3.2  ESTABLISHED AIR RESOURCE DECISION-MAKING PROCEDURES

      Ten years ago, before computer simulation had been applied to air
pollution analyses, regional studies of pollutant concentrations, air

pollution effects, emission sources, and other data were used in regional
air resource planning.  The "roll-back technique" developed by Dr.  Ralph

I. Larsen was used to calculate reduction in source emissions needed to
meet air quality goals.
1Ibid., pp. 721-722.
                                   22

-------
      With the development of the Implementation Planning Program (IPP),
a mathematical simulation model is now available for evaluating the ef-
fectiveness of the emission control regulations contained in implementation
plans.  The model measures the effectiveness of emission regulations and
compares predicted air quality to the air quality standards of a region.
3.2.1  Nashville Metropolitan Area Air Resource Management Plan
      A major air .pollution study was undertaken in the Nashville Metro-
politan Area by the U. S. Public Health Service, in cooperation with
Vanderbilt University and state and local agencies, between 1957 and 1959.
The primary purpose of the study was to "assist the citizens and govern-
ment of the Nashville Metropolitan Area in understanding the nature of
air pollution problems and in developing a course of action to improve
air quality and assure clean air in the future by establishing an air re-
source management program."   An extensive study was conducted of pollu-
tant concentrations, pollution effects, community perception, sources of
emissions, etc., ambient air quality goals were developed, and procedures
for the development of an air resource management program were suggested.
      In the report of the Nashville project, the state-of-the-art of air
resource planning is defined as follows:
            The information presented in this report, although among the
            most complete for any community in the world, does not describe
            all aspects of the air pollution situation in absolute terms.
            This deficiency cannfct be avoided because the resources of
            that basic data in the air pollution field are still limited,
            although they are expanding as a result of extensive, current
            research programs.  In some matters, conclusions must be
            based on the best judgments possible in view of the factual
            information available.  To delay action until all the deci-
            sions could be based on complete and exhaustive investigation ~
            would permit air pollution problems to become even more acute.
 J. D.  Williams and N.  G.  Edmisten, An Air Resource Management Plan for
 Che Nashville Metropolitan Area.  U.S.  P.H.S.  Publication,  No. 999-AP-18,
 p. 1,  September 1965.
 Ibid.,  p.  9.

                                    23

-------
      To calculate the percent of source reduction needed to meet the air
quality goals, the Nashville study employed the Larsen roll-back technique,
a method which is not necessarily sensitive to the geographical distribu-
tion of air pollutants within the region but focuses instead upon major
emission reductions needed to lower regionwide air pollutant concentration.
The technique is used to compare the actual percent reduction in emissions
with the desired percent reduction (a level somewhere between the exist-
ing pollutant concentration and the background concentration).  A somewhat
simplified illustration of the procedure is shown in Figure 3-2.   For
more detailed information, the Nashville report cited previously and
Larsen's paper in the APCA Journal  may be consulted.

 3.2.2   Implementation Planning  Under The Clean Air  Amendments of  1970
       Since  the  Nashville  study,  air pollution simulation modeling  has
 reached a level  of sophistication such that  it can  effectively assist  the
 air resource planner in evaluating the distribution of  pollutant  concentra-
 tions  within a  region.   The most  important contribution of  the model is  its
 ability to predict the pollutant  concentrations  both before and after  emis-
 sion control.
       Under  the  Clean Air  Amendments of 1970,  implementation plan guide-
 lines  recommend  the use of either the  rollback technique or diffusion
 modeling in  evaluating the ability of  emission control  regulations  to  meet
 primary or secondary regional air quality standards.  The  rollback  techni-
 que is still desirable in  some  AQCRs because of  emission and air  quality
 data limitations,  the nature of the air pollution problem and the resources
 required to  conduct the analysis.   The Implementation Planning Program
 (IPP)  is the most  commonly used model  for strategy  analysis.  In  IPP,  a
 Control Strategy Model analyzes the effectiveness of control strategies
 on sources by calculating  the reduction in emissions from point  sources,
 computing the annual costs for controlling point sources, and printing
 a visual display of predicted air pollution concentrations  following
 application  of  a proposed  control strategy.
  R.  I.  Larsen,  "A Method for Determining  Source  Reduction  Required  to Meet
 Air  Quality Standards," Journal of the Air Pollution  Control  Association,
 Vol.  II,  No.  2,  pp.  71-76,  February 1961.
                                     24

-------
                                              —  EXISTING CONCENTRATION
                                                  DESIRED AIR QUALITY
                                                  GOAL  CONCENTRATION
                                                  BACKGROUND
                                                  CONCENTRATION
            GEOGRAPHICAL  DISTRIBUTION
            OF POLLUTANT  CONCENTRATION
            IN REGION
            CROSS-SECTION  OF REGION
(PERCENT OF SOURCE      ,nft   (A-C)  -  (B -  C)
 REDUCTION NEEDED)   "   IUU  .     A-C
 WHERE:
        A =  EXISTING CONCENTRATION

        B =  DESIRED AIR QUALITY GOAL CONCENTRATION

        C =  BACKGROUND CONCENTRATION
             Figure 3-2.   Roll-Back Technique

-------
       Figure  3-3 illustrates  the  use  of  the  Control  Strategy  Model  in
 cross-sectional analyses.   Alternative  strategies  are tested  within the
 model,  beginning with the  most lenient  control regulations  (strategy 1)
 and  progressing to the most stringent (strategy 5).   Strategy 5,  defined
 as  "maximum technology," requires maximum feasible control  technology for
..all  sources,  disregarding, economic factors and availability of control
 hardware and  fuels.
       Figure  3-4 shows pollutant  concentrations in the Metropolitan
 Cincinnati Interstate Air  Quality Control Region as  estimated by  the IPP
 diffusion model before application of control  strategies.   Figure 3-5
 shows  the IPP-predicted pollutant concentrations resulting  from the control
 strategy that was selected as a basis for preparing  emission  control regu-
 lations for the Cincinnati Region.*
       The IPP model- represents a  significant improvement over earlier
 methods, in that regulations  of greater  or lesser  stringency  can  now be
 compared for  various political jurisdictions in an AQCR and the resulting
 distributions .of pollutant concentrations analyzed.   Acceptance of  a
 control strategy is  at present based  only on the predicted  pollutant
 concentration relative to  the air quality standard',  however,  without
 regard to regional and national economic impact.   The economic distribu-
 tion of impact on sources  and benefits  to receptors  are-likewise  not
 considered.   Moreover^ the strategies are not,  in  general,  related  to
 regional environmental and urban-planning goals and  objectives.   There
 is  a need for a broader analytical approach  which  includes  examination
 of  long-term  land use plans as well as plans for regional economic
 development.
 *A detailed  description of  IPP  is  presented  in  Chapter  6.0'of  this  report.

                                    26

-------
            t
NJ
             LU
             CJ
             O
             O
             O
             D-
STRATEGY 1
                                    STRATEGY 2
            >l
                                    STRATEGY 3
                                    STRATEGY  ^




                                    STRATEGY  5
                                               TIME
                                  Figure 3-3.  The Testing of Emission Control Strategies

-------
                                         KENTON    CAMPBELL
«  1969 NASN, CAMP
o  1968/1959 Northern Kentucky Network
   Concentration  in
           Figure 3-4.  Annual Arithmetic Mean  Concentrations of
                        Suspended Particulate Pollutants as Estimated
                        by Diffusion Model for  Existing Conditions.
                                     28

-------
Note:  Annual Average Concentrations in
      Figure 3-5.  Predicted Ground-Level Concentrations Following
                  Application of Proposed Control Strategy
                                     29

-------
   . 4.0  CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR REGIONAL AIR RESOURCE DECISION-MAKING

      In the sections which follow, the decision-making structure of
regional air pollution cost-benefit analysis is examined as a basis for
the development of a cost-benefit model.  The air resource problem, region-
al decision-making objectives, and types of criteria for evaluating
changes in regional welfare are discussed.  Relevant aspects of cost/
benefit analysis theory are not discusse'd here but presented in Appendix A.
4.1  OVERVIEW
      Deficiencies in the current air resource planning approach were noted
in the preceding chapters.  Particular emphasis was placed upon the need
for evaluating the impacts of air resource plads as they directly and in-
directly affect the welfare of society.  The approach suggested in this
section is designed to provide a framework for such an evaluation.
      Two types of economic effects can be distinguished, those that in-
crease the overall level of economic activity by reducing costs and/or
increasing productivity (positive income effects), and those that redis-
tribute resources without increasing the net economic level (redistribution
effects).
      Through a consideration of these effects, changes in the well-being
of the individuals affected, the metropolitan.area, and the society in
general may be defined.  In a cost/benefit evaluation, actual changes in
well-being (i.e., welfare) are compared with desired changes (the goals
or objectives of the region).  These goals provide a useful framework for
discussing cost/benefit analysis of air resource planning.
      Figure 4-1 illustrates the air resource decision-making process and
the role of economic analysis in evaluating the ability of alternative
solutions to satisfy planning objectives.1  The combined procedures of
economic, cost/benefit, and systems analysis (such as the procedures
 This report treats the "decision-making process" in a very general sense.
U docs not investigate the alternative levels of decision-making within
public and private sectors.
                                    31
PRECEDING PAGE BLANK

-------
   KNOWLEDGE
   OF GOALS
   "KNOWLEDGE OF
   PROBLEM AND
   ALTERNATIVE
   SOLUTIONS
                           r
STATEMENT OF AN
ALTERNATIVE
SOLUTION
(I.E., EMISSION
CONTROL STRATEGY)
       1
STATEMENT OF
AIR RESOURCE
PLAN OBJECTIVES
   INDICATORS
   OF WELFARE
                       ECONOMIC
                       ANALYSIS
         Figure 4-1.  Air Resource Decision-Making Process
                                 32

-------
presented in this report and others) are directed toward the development

of social and economic indicators (evaluation criteria).  These indicators

form a basis for evaluating goals in the following categories:

          •   Economic efficiency—Increased welfare for the
              region, i.e., increased aggregate income and
              productivity.

          •   Economic redistribution—The desirable distri-
              bution of benefits among income classes.

          •   Economic growth and stabilization—Stability of
              employment and regional product, as well as
              growth in regional income, employment, and
              other economic indicators.

      Within the analytical framework, the constraints on an air resource

program must be identified in order to ensure the development of correct

assumptions and analytical techniques.  Seven categories of constraints

have been identified by one author.*  The categories, followed  by examples

relevant to air pollution, are:

          1.  Physical—Fuel availability, control hardware,
              technological developments, etc.

          2.  Legal—Promulgation of proposed regulations.
                                         •
          3.  Administrative—Staffing and enforcement of.
              regulations once they have been promulgated;
              purchase and operation of surveillance
              equipment.
          4.  Distributional—Prevention of severe economic
              impact to small sources or the desirable allo-
              cation of clean burning fuels to certain source
              categories.

          5.  Political—Opposition to controls by sources,
              fuel suppliers, and other institutions.

          6.  Financial or Budget—Resource limitations of
              control agencies and emission sources which
              prevent instantaneous compliance.

          7.  Traditional, Social, and Religious—Opposition.
              to certain control regulations (such as a ban
              on burning leaves) because of social custom.
*Categories applicable to all public programs;  presented in 0.  Eckstein,
"A Survey of the Theory of Public Expenditure Criteria," Public Finances
Needs, Sources and Utilization,  National Bureau of Economic Research,
Princeton University Press, Princeton,  N.  J., pp.  43-9-494,  1961.
                                    33

-------
Political and other constraints which prevent immediate solution to air
pollution problems should be identified.  Such factors as the need for
additional effects information, time of enforcement of regulations, and
installation of control hardware must be taken into consideration.
      The welfare indicators which are used in the evaluation of goals may
be consistent with certain regional planning objectives and detrimental to
others.  The role of the decision-maker is to determine which of the
regional objectives are most important in relation to both short-term and
long-term goals.
      The number of alternative solutions proposed by the analyst must be
sufficient to permit marginal evaluations, that  is, evaluations which con-
sider the additional benefits (or increments, of  welfare)' resulting from
marginal reallocations of funds of marginal increases in the stringency of
emission control regulations.  Policy decisions  will ultimately be based
upon the evaluation of these objectives and welfare indicators.
4.2   PROBLEMS IN AIR RESOURCE PLANNING
      The schedule of events specified in the air pollution control
legislation for regions is shown in Figure 4-2.   Air resource policy
decisions are being based on guidelines established by the Air Pollution
Control Office.  A "crystal ball" forecast of future conditions in a
hypothetical Air Quality Control Region (AQCR) is illustrated in Figure
4-3.  To meet the primary and secondary air quality standards, the air
resource planner must establish policies in the  following areas:
          1.  General Stringency of Control—How efficient must
              emission control He in order to optimize the welfare
              of the region relative to the air  resource and other
              urban goals?
          2.  Compliance Schedule—How quickly can the region move
              toward the optimum-welfare condition, taking into
              account the welfare of the regional'economy?
          3.  Inducement Approach—What combination of emission
              regulations, emission taxes, land-use planning,
              product laws, etc., represents the most efficient
              and equitable approach in reaching the desired
              objectives?
          4.  Locational Aspects—What is the most efficient
              and equitable manner in which emission limitations
              can be applied relative to geographical location
              in the AQCR?
                                    34

-------
SCHEDULE
OF —
EVENTS
h

CLEAN
AIR
ACT
ESTABLISH
REGIONS
CRITERIA
AND
CONTROL
TECHNIQUES
AIR
QUALITY
STANDARDS
IMPLEMENTATION
PLAN
•
ENFORCE
PLAN
ATTAIN
DESIRED
AIR
QUALITY
<•->
REGIONAL
POLLUTANT
CONCENTRATION
                                                                                                     EXISTING
                                                                                                     AIR
                                                                                                     QUALITY
                                                                           AIR
                                                                           QUALITY
                                                                           GOAL
                                                                                               (AQ)	
                                                      TIME
                                 Figure  4-2.  The Path to  Clean  Air

-------
 REGIONAL AIR
 1'OI.LUTANT
 CONCENTRATION
NET
AGGREGATE
COSTS  ($)
NET
AGGREGATE
BENEFITS ($)
                                     TIME
              Figure 4-3.   Flow of Costs and Benefits Over Time

                                      36

-------
Effective air resource planning will require more sophisticated tools to
answer these questions than have thus far been available.
4.3  DECISION-MAKING OBJECTIVES
      Once regional goals have been defined, the air resource decision-maker
will decide upon essential planning objectives.   Different levels of objec-
tives will be identified, perhaps as follows:
          •   Air resource planning objectives.
          •   Environmental planning objectives
          •   Urban planning objectives
The objectives  of the air resource planner may  or may not be consistent
with those of other government planners.   Total  regional welfare which is
difficult, if not impossible, to determine should be the deciding factor
when conflicts in objectives arise.
      The formal procedure currently recommended for the development of
implementation plans fails to provide for sufficient consideration of the
various regional planning objectives.  Although  outside the scope of the
present project, the development of more  sophisticated guidelines for
regional objectives by APCO is encouraged.  Some objectives which might
be considered in the AQCR decision-making process include:
          •   Regional economic growth.
          •   Increased public and private investment.
          •   Creation of new job opportunities.
          •   Net inducement of private investment in
              labor into the region.
          •   Decrease in social cost of  living  in region.
          •   Increase in fiscal capacity of central-city
              tax base.
          •   Enticement of moderate-income households
              into central city.
          •   Revitalization of commercial core  (Central
              Business District).
          •   Expansion and support of central-city institutions.
          •   Increased aesthetic appeal  of central-city and
              region as a whole for residents'and tourists.
                                    37

-------
4.4  EVALUATION CRITERIA
      Regional planning objectives and evaluation criteria will influence
the selection of air resource analytical procedures.   Welfare criteria
may be used to reflect the changes in community well-being that result from
air resource planning activities.  These welfare indicators must be de-
signed to detect and, in some cases, measure advances toward the various
goals of the air resource program.
      Procedures for identifying specific criteria for analyses of govern-
ment programs are outlined by H.T. Hatry,* as part of an attempt to clarify
the basic concepts of governmental program planning analysis.  Hatry also
identifies specific criteria for use in evaluating alternative program
proposals for carrying out major state and local governmental functions.
      It^ is important that each criterion be relevant to the specific
problem under consideration.  Criteria applied in the solution of a specific
problem should cover all major effects relative to the objectives.  Ideally,
each of the criteria should be capable of meaningful quantification, although
for air resource programs it may be necessary to utilize purely qualitative
measures.   The criteria selected must relate to governmental objectives.
      In the study cited above*, criteria are grouped into seven major
program areas:
            •  Personal safety
            •  Health
            •  Intellectual development, personal enrichment
            •  Satisfactory home and community environment
            •  Economic satisfaction and satisfactory work opportunities
            •  Satisfactory leisure time opportunities
            •  Transportation - communication - location
*H.T. Hatry, "Criteria for Evaluation in"Planning State and Local Programs,
 "In H. H. Hinrichs and G. M. Taylor, eds., Program Budgeting and Benefit -
 Cost Analysis, Goodyear Publishing Co., Pacific Palisades, Calif., pp. 94-
 119, 1969

                                    38

-------
Most governmental programs can be evaluated by criteria that fall within one
or two of these categories.  For air pollution problems, however, relevant
criteria may be found in all seven categories.
      Monetary criteria are essential in the evaluation of air pollution
programs, but the problems encountered in developing such criteria are
quite complex since most air pollution effects are intangible (i.e., not
readily measured).  Monetary criteria which can be used to evaluate changes
in gross income and economic activity in a region include:
            •  Manufacturing value added
            •  Retail and wholesale sales
            •  Amount of bank deposits
            •  Industrial capital expenditures
      Due to the complexities associated with identification, assessment,
and evaluation of air pollution effects, it is assumed that air resource
decision-making in the near future will be based primarily on qualitative
criteria and non-monetary quantitative criteria (such as documented effects
as listed in the pollutant "criteria documents").   Evaluation criteria must
be developed which are based on the criteria documents and other pertinent
literature.
4.5  APPLICATION OF COST/BENEFIT ANALYSIS TO AIR RESOURCE DECISION-MAKING
      The aim of cost/benefit analysis is to maximize the present value
of all benefits less that of all costs incurred, subject to specified
constraints.  .Cost/benefit analysis has been considered for use in the
evaluation of transportation systems, criminal rehabilitation programs,
urban renewal projects, and other social programs.  Economists Prest and
Turvey have stated that "cost/benefit analysis can also be applied to
proposed changes in laws or regulations, to new pricing schemes and the
like."1
      In air pollution control, C/B analysis can be employed to compare
the social costs and benefits resulting from a potential air resource
  op. Cit. P. 686.
                                     39

-------
policy with those to be expected from a continuation of the existing level
of effort (the "base alternative"), as shown in Figure 4-4.  After defining
the project life (the period of time over which costs and benefits will be
measured), the costs and benefits of alternative air resource policies are
computed and discounted back to the base year for purposes of comparative
analysis.  The resulting data may then be used in the evaluation of
alternative policies.
      Determination of the project life is an important factor in the
design of a cost/benefit analysis study, since various costs and benefits
are frequently realized at substantially different points in time.  Project
life is estimated rather subjectively, on the basis of an assessment of
such factors as physical lifespan, technological change, shifts in demand,
and emergence of competing products.  For water resource projects involving
the construction'of dams, project life may be defined as 50 or 100 years
for dams that are expected to perform for 150 years.  In air pollution
planning, a shorter project life is desirable because of the following
factors:
          •   Frequent changes, in air resource requirements
          •   Rapid depreciation of control equipment (15 years or so)
          •   Obsolesence of current control equipment because of
              technological innovations
          •   Rapid technological and conceptual changes throughout
              the relatively new field of air resource management.
      In conclusion, there are numerous other characteristics of the
cost/benefit analysis framework which have been studied elsewhere in the
application of C/B to other public programs.  An investigation of such
other factors is not within the scope of this report but is recommended
for future research.  Hopefully, this chapter has served to identify a
few of the more important aspects which must be considered In the develop-
ment of cost/benefit procedures for the analysis of air pollution control
strategies.
                                    40

-------
     (AQ),
_
§
o
(X
O
*—r
o
UJ
QC
     (AQ)g
                                      AIR QUALITY  RESULTING FROM CURRENT
                                        CONTROL  AGENCY  "LEVEL  OF EFFORT"
                        BASE
                        YEAR
     AIR QUALITY
     RESULTING FROM
     REGIONAL AIR
     RESOURCE POLICY
              1970
               4-
1971
 1972        1973          1974

        TIME  (YEARS)

	   PROJECT LIFE
                                                                          1975
                                                             1976
 197?


->
             Figure 4-4.  The Concept of- Air Pollution Cost/Benefit Analysis

-------
                 5.0  OVERVIEW OF THE COST/BENEFIT MODEL
      The preceding chapters have focused on the need for improved
analytical procedures to support air resource planning.  The conceptual
framework of the decision-making process has been identified, and the use
of cost/benefit analysis in this process has been discussed.
      The cost/benefit model is introduced in this chapter and alternative
methods of model utilization are identified.  The introductory material
provided here serves as a transition from the previously cited needs for
a conceptual framework for analytical studies to the practical procedures
presented in Chapter 7.0 (Control Cost Estimating Procedures) and Chapter
8.0 (Benefit Model).  Some applications of the C/B Model are presented in
Chapter 9.0.
      The C/B Model is an outgrowth of the Implementation Planning Program
(IPP).  The C/B Model is the last module of the Regional Air Pollution
Analysis (RAPA) system as it was initially envisioned in 1968.  A simple
flow diagram of the C/B Model and its relation to IPP is shown in Figure
5-1.  A general description of the model will serve as an introduction to
the C/B system.
      Two outputs of IPP now being used in regional air quality decision-
making are:  (1) point source control costs, and, (2) air quality display
(as previously cited in Chapter 2.0).  Point source control costs are
estimated for each identified pollution source with particulate or sulfur
dioxide emission rates greater than 24 tons per year (the commonly
accepted cut-off point).  The control costs are calculated on a source-by-
source basts by hypothetically applying to each source the control system
needed to comply with the emission strategy under investigation.   The air
quality display is a two dimensional plot of pollution concentration (in
the form of isopleths) within an AQCR.   The outputs of IPP serve as inputs
to the C/B Model, as shown in Figure 5-1.
      The efforts of this study (and the follow-on demonstration of the
C/B Model) have been directed at the development of the Benefit Model.
Procedures for estimating control agency and area source control costs are
identified in Chapter 7.0 but have not. been developed as part of this pro-
ject.   Thus, point source control costs (which are generally a significant
                                                 PRECEDING PAGE BLANIf

-------
                   IMPLEMENTATION PLANNING PROGRAM  (IPP)
     INPUTS

• AIR QUALITY DATA

» METEOROLOGICAL DATA
• EMISSION  INVENTORY
• CONTROL TECHNIQUES
  AND COSTS
CONTROL
STRATEGIES
  CONTROL SUPPLIER
  FUNCTION
• RECEPTOR DATA
  DAMAGE
  FUNCTIONS
• CONTROL AGENCY
  COSTS

                             ATMOSPHERIC
                             DIFFUSION
                             MODEL
                                                          CALIBRATION
                                                          PROCEDURE
                                                        EXISTING
                                                        AIR QUALITY
                                                        DISPLAY
                             CONTROL
                             COST
                             FILE
                                              CONTROL
                                              STRATEGY
                                              MODEL
                                                        POINT SOURCE
                                                        CONTROL COSTS
                                        AIR QUALITY
                                        DISPLAY
                                                AREA SOURCE
                                                CONTROL COSTS
                                    BENEFIT
                                    MODEL
                                      REGIONAL
                                      BENEFITS
                                                               REGIONAL
                                                               CONTROL
                                                               COST
       Figure 5-1.   Regional Air Pollution Cost/Benefit Model
                                     44

-------
portion of the total regional control cost)  are the only estimates of tlie
cost of air pollution control available at this time.
      The Benefit Model relates predicted control strategy pollutant
concentrations to receptors and damage functions.  The air pollutant-
receptor relationship is an estimate of receptor exposure (i.e., dosage).
The damage function, which relates the annual cost of  air pollution damage
to pollution concentrations, applied to the exposure estimate determines
the damage cost estimate.
      The Control Supplier Function, drawn in Figure 5-1, is a procedure
for estimating the type and quantity of resources demanded for the control
of air pollution for each strategy.   Such an estimate  of resources demanded
is important for economic modeling.   The need for this procedure has been
identified and an elementary method  of developing such data is presented
in Appendix U.
5.1  VALUE OF THE COST/BENEFIT MODEL
      The design philosophy of the Cost/Benefit Model  has been based on
the use of data which are either readily available or  which are identifiable
and capable of being collected within a reasonable period of time.  The
models are thus practical devices which use the best decision-making
information available.
      As a simulation tool, the Cost/Benefit Model will be useful for
analysis of economic efficiency and  economic redistribution of factors
associated with alternative emission control strategies for an Air Quality
Control Region (AQCR).   The model may be used in sensitivity analyses to
test various inputs such as damage functions.  The effectiveness of alter-
native land use policies may also be determined for individual political
jurisdictions within a region.  Finally, the model can be used in simula-
tion tests of research data on air quality and pollution effects.
      As the design of the system progresses, problems concerning the
sensitivity of data and other related considerations will arise.  Analysis
of these problems will improve the accuracy of regional air resource
derision-making.   The simulation model will make a significant contribu-
t ion to the understanding of the decision-making process and of the total
("•.pact of air pollution control policies.

-------
'>.:'.  AI.TKRNATLVK TYL-KS or MODKI.S
      Two typi-:; oL" :; imulation models can be applied In i-valuat i n>', alLrrna-
tivo control strategies, cross-sectional models and longitudinal models.
Cross-sectional models of which the IPP and regional econometric models
arc examples are somewhat simpler than longitudinal models.
      The concept of a cross-sectional model is illustrated in Figure 5-2.
As is shown, the conditions resulting from a control strategy are analyzed
nt one given point in time.  Existing conditions (i.e., the base alterna-
tive) are first analyzed, and the effects of alternative policies are then
evaluated, with the sssumption that all responses will occur instantaneous-
ly.  This method of evaluation, however, is not consistent with the theo-
retical framework of C/B analysis, which requires that the costs and
benefits of a proposed policy be evaluated over the defined project life
and measured relative to the base alternative.  There is, nonetheless, a
great deal to be .gained by- cross-sectional analysis.  The effort and cost
involved in forecasting conditions and the uncertainty of these forecasts,
especially in such areas as fuel availability, process and control tech-
nologies, etc., can make the use of longitudinal models impractical.
Finally, the IPP model has the capability of analyzing future conditions
and, in fact, has been used to evaluate 1980 conditions in the development
of implementation plans for AQCRs.
      Longitudinal C/B analysis traces costs and benefits to some future
time and discounts cost estimates back to a base year (see Figure 5-3).
The analysis may, for example, estimate costs and benefits annually from
1970 through 1975, assuming a project life of 5 years.  The analysis should
be sensitive to progress (in the form of improved air quality, thus, bene-
fits which will occur during specified increments during the project life),
as well as to variations in control costs.
      Such an analysis is more realistic than the cross-sectional analysis,
since costs and benefits do not occur instantaneously in real situations.
Sources initially spend large sums for the analysis of emissions control
problems, research, and equipment installation.  The benefits from a con-
trol strategy are not immediately evident, since control systems must be
designed, installed, and put into operation before benefits to receptors
will be noted.   The procedure of analyzing costs and benefits over time
                                    46

-------
          (AQ)
REGIONAL
POLLUTANT
CONCENTRATION
          (AQ),
                           1970
1971
                                                     XX
              (///////
                                                                       ANALYSIS OF EXISTING CONDITIONS
                                                                       ANALYSIS OF CONDITIONS UNDER A
                                                                       REGIONAL CONTROL STRATEGY
1972        1973
TIME (YEARS)
1974
1975
                    Figure 5-2.  Form of Regional Cross-Sectional Analysis

-------
                 (AQ)
                 (AQ)
                     72
    REGIONAL
    POLLUTANT
    CONCENTRATION
                 (AQ)
                     73
oo
                 (AQ)

                 (AQ),
74
                                   1970
                         1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
                                                            TIME (YEARS) •* (AQ)  = EXISTING AIR QUALITY
                                                                           (AQ)6 = AIR QUALITY GOAL
                                                                               g
                              Figure 5-3.  Longitudinal  Cost/Benefit Study of Air Quality

-------
and discounting these values back to a base year is utilized because of
the time discrepancy in the flow of costs and benefits.
      In addition to the data needed for a cross-sectional analysis, a
longitudinal model will require forecasts of (1) population, (2) control
technology, (3) control hardware and fuel prices, (4) sources,  and, (5)
emissions.  A method must also be developed whereby the schedule for
source compliance may be estimated.  This method must evaluate  the con-
straints which prevent instantaneous compliance by sources, including
availability of control hardware and alternative fuels, political lobbying,
enforcement procedure, and other factors.  Longitudinal analysis thus in-
volves repeated use of the cross-sectional model in combination with
additional technical and economic forecasts'.
      The decision was made during this effort to concentrate on initial
development of a cross-sectional C/B Model, due to limitations  in the
availability and accuracy of data on sources, emissions, damage functions,
etc.  On the basis of an evaluation of this cross-sectional model, a
decision will be made concerning the additional development of  a longitu-
dinal C/B Model.
5.3  COST/BENEFIT MODEL UTILIZATION
      The Cost/Benefit Model was designed with two immediate end-uses in
                                                               •
mind.   The first end-use is in welfare economic studies of air  pollution
control strategies in an AQCR.  Control cost and benefit estimates, which
are the outputs of the model, can be used directly for evaluating effi-
ciency and equity considerations of .control strategies.  In this applica-
tion,  the cost/benefit ratios of alternative strategies may be  weighed.
The distribution of benefits and costs among certain groups of  receptors
within the AQCR can also be examined.   The model can be used in this
manner to evaluate air quality standards, land-use plans,  industrial
development siting and other regional plans.
      A flow diagram of the C/B Model as used directly in  decision-making
is illustrated in Figure 5-4.  The model, as shown in the  Figure,  has been
integrated into the decision-making process cited earlier'  in this report.
The direct application of C/B analysis represents one type of economic
evaluation for alternative strategies.

                                    49

-------
                                             i AIR QUALITY.
                                              DATA
                                             . METEOROLOG-
                                              ICAL DATA

                                             i EMISSION

. k

ATMOSPHt r ;C
DIFFUSION
WCDEL

	 ^
CAUi'.A'lCN
PKCCFDuSE
1
             r
STATEMENT OF
AN ALTERNATIVE
SOLUTION, (IE,
EMISSION CON-
TROL STRATEGY)


TECHNIQUES
AND COSTS
CONTROL
COST FILE


—k.

i
CONTROL
MODEL
AIR C J
DISPiA
« 	 1
1
                       IDENTIFIABLE EFFECTS (IE, COSTS AND BENEFITS) NOT
                       ADEQUATELY ME-ASUREABLt FOR THE FUNCTIONAL FORM
PCII.I
SOURCE
CONTSCL
COST;
                                                                CONTROL
                                                                SUPPLIER
                                                                FUNCTIONS
                                                                • DIRECT EFFECTS
                                                                • ADJUSTMENTS
                                                                • MARKET EFFECTS
                                                                                  /REGIONAL^
                                                                                 I BENEFITS I
Figure 5-4.   Direct  Application of  C/B  Model  in  Strategy Analysis

-------
      But, this type of economic evaluation is  limited  in  scope.   The
resulting estimates of control costs and benefits derived  from  the direct
utilization of the model are not reflected as impacts on the  economic
activitiy of the region or the nation.  The reallocation of resources  in
the economy, which is expected from an air pollution control  policy, is
not reflected in the C/B Model.  Impacts on such economic  indicators as
employment, capital investment, regional income, value  added, and  others
are not measured.  Air pollution policies have  an effect on such  indicators
on the region and the nation and should be evaluated.
      To measure the impacts of control policies on the economy,  the con-
trol cost and benefit estimates from the C/B Model must be evaluated in a
series of economic models.  CONSAD Research Corporation has developed  an
economic model system for this purpose (see Figure 5-5).  The CONSAD mode]
system has been designed to determine the economic effects of air  pollution
policies on regions and the nation.  The economic model system  currently
consists of two major components, namely, a regional economic model
(applied to 100 of the Nation's AQCRs) and a national input/output (I/O)
model (see Figure 5-6).  The regional economic  model determines the effects
of air pollution control costs and benefits on  an open  regional economy.
The nationa] I/O system is introduced to serve  the role of the  external
markets (provide inter-regional feedback) for the regional economy, and
also to measure the structural change of the national economy upon air
pollution control to the 100 AQCRs.   The economic model system measures
effects of air pollution strategies in terms of changes in unemployment,
value added, income, and other measures of economic activity.
      This report focuses on the utilization of the C/B Model by  itself.
In this manner, the costs and benefits are used directly in decision-making.
When the economic model system is utilized, the benefits must be  converted
into a form which reflects changes in disposable income and productivity of
labor and capital.  This report does not focus on such economic  evaluations,
See referenced document  for ;
of the economic model system.
See referenced document  for a discussion of the principles and procedures
 Tor a complete description of the economic model system,  see An  Kcpiiomjc
.''!. - '"I Svi-.tcn. for t':v:- Asru^a-rnt of 1: ffects of Air Pollution Abaf oiiien c ,
(Vi:;::AI> Kcs<.-ai:cii Co:-po:.;.it..ion, 1'it t.sburgh , Pa., April  13 ,  1971.
                                     r.
                                     '.i

-------
> AIRQUA.'.ITY
 DAT.'.     "

. METEOROLOG
 ICAL DATA

• EMISSION
 INVENTORY'

• CONTROL
 TECHNIQUES
 AND COSTS
                              IMPLEMENTATION PLANNING PROGRAM
                                        (TRW SYSTEMS!



ATMOSPHERIC
DIFFUSION
MODEL


CALIBRATION
PROCEDU8E
1
CONTROL
COST FILE
                                                                    EXISTING
                                                                    AIR QUALITY
                                                                    DISPLAY
CONTROL
STRATEGY
MODEL
* 1

1
to
                                                                      POINT
                                                                      SOURCE
                                                                      CONTROL
                                                                      COST
                              . CONTROL
                               SUPPLIER
                               FUNCTIONS
                              • RECEPTOR
                               DATA
                              • DAMAGE
                               FUNCTIONS
                               • DIRECT EFFECTS
                               • ADJUSTMENTS
                               • MARKET EFFECTS
                  COST/BENEf IT MODEL
             (PARTIALLY UNDER DEVELOPMENT)
I      ICAKIIA
                                                                                                          ECONOMIC MODEL SYSTEM
                                                                                                          (CONSAD RESEARCH CORP)
                                                                                          REGIONAL VARIABLES
                                                                                          AT PREVIOUS YEAR:
                                                                                           VALUE ADDED
                                                                                           CAPITAL STOCK
                                                                                           CONSUMPTION
                                                                                           REGIONAL INCOME
                                                                                    POPULATION AND
                                                                                    MIGRATION
                                                                                     GOVERNMENT
                                                                                     EXPENDITURE
                                                                                  REGIONAL INDUSTRIAL
                                                                                  INVESTMENT RE-
                                                                                  QUIRED BY AIR
                                                                                  POLLUTION ABATEMENT
                                                                                  STRATEGY
                                                                                                            NATIONAL
                                                                                                            INPUT/OUTPUT
                                                                                                            MODEL
                                                                                           ECONOMIC GAINS
                                                                                           OF AIR POLLUTION
                                                                                           CONTROL
                                                                                                            REGIONAL
                                                                                                            ECONOMETRIC
                                                                                                            MODEL
                                                                                                                                       R[GIONAL INCOME
                                                                                                                                       AND CONSUMPTION
                                                                                                                                         INDUSTRIAL
                                                                                                                                          OUTPUT
                                                                                                                                          INVESTMENT
                                                                                                                                          EMPLOYMENT
                                                                                                                                          CAPITAL SIOCK
                                                                                                                                   REGIONAL
                                                                                                                                    UNEMPLOYMENT
                                                                                                                                    LABOR FORCE
                                                                                                            CHANGES OF REGIONAL
                                                                                                            INCOME, CONSUMP-
                                                                                                            TION, VALUE ADDtO,
                                                                                                            INVESTMENT AND EM-
                                                                                                            PLOYMENT BY INDUS-
                                                                                                            TRY, REGIONAL UNEM-
                                                                                                            PLOYMENT GENERATED
                                                                                                            BY DIRECT COSTS AND
                                                                                                            BENEFITS OF EACH
                                                                                                            ABATEMENT STRATEGY
                                           Figure  5-5.   Use of  C/B Model  with Economic Model  System

-------
-O MODEL AND INTER-
 REGIONAL FEEDBACK
                 ~l
r
    NATIONAL
    I-O MODEL
     REGIONAL
     MARKET
     SHARE
     MATRIX
                REGIONAL MODEL
                                   MANUFAC-
                                   TURING
                                   INDUSTRIES
          I
                                 REGIONAL
                                 ECONOMY
                                 • INCOME
                                 • CONSUMPTION
                                 • GOVERNMENT
          I
                            ELECTRICITY
                            AND FUEL
                            DEMAND
                                   REGIONAL
                                   LABOR
                                   MARKET
                 _J        L_
                  Figure 5-6. Major Components of the Model

-------
                6.0  CONTROL COST ESTIMATING PROCEDURES
      The IPP model currently predicts only control costs for point sources
 (see Section 5.0 for a discussion on this limitation).  Since the social
 cost of controlling air pollution includes more than point source control
 costs, this chapter focuses on the development of other cost estimating
 procedures which may, in the future, supplement the point source control
 costs.  The major cost categories recommended for inclusion in the model
 are identified as "area source control costs" and "control agency costs."
      In addition, this chapter presents a detailed description of the
 Implementation Planning Program (IPP) and its uses.  This presentation is
 important because IPP provides the control cost estimates and the air
 quality display which are the inputs to the Benefit Model (Chapter 7.0).
 6.1  IMPLEMENTATION PLANNING PROGRAM
      The Implementation Planning Program is illustrated in Figure 6-1.
 The heart of the IPP is the Atmospheric Diffusion Model, which predicts
ambient concentrations of pollutants in an AQCR by mathematically determin-
 ing the dispersion of pollutants from sources.   Input to the model is in
the form of an emission inventory which lists the major sources of pollutants
and gives detailed engineering parameters for the sources of pollution and
the emissions generated.  Emission contributions from sources that cannot
be identified individually are aggregated to form "area' sources."
Meteorological data are included on wind speed,  wind direction, mixing
depth, and other phenomena characterizing the transport mechanism whereby
pollutants are transmitted from sources to receptors.
      To improve the accuracy of the diffusion model, a calibration proce-
dure is-used to compare predicted pollutant concentrations with measured
air quality values.  The procedure adjusts for errors in the diffusion
model which result from inaccuracies in the mathematical diffusion equa-
tion, inaccurate source-emission and meteorological data, irregularities
in the topography of the region (which the model assumes to be a flat
plain),  and other deviations.   The Atmospheric Diffusion Model thus pre-
dicts the concentration and distribution of pollutants for the AQCR with
reasonable accuracy.
                                     55
PRECEDING PAGE BLANK

-------
          INPUTS
      AIR QUALITY
      DATA

      METEOROLOGICAL
      DATA
      EMISSION
      INVENTORY
      CONTROL
      TECHNIQUES
      AND COSTS
      CONTROL
      STRATEGIES
ATMOSPHERIC
DIFFUSION
MODEL
                                                                CALIBRATION
                                                                PROCEDURE
                           EXISTING
                           AIR QUALITY
                           DISPLAY
CONTROL
COST
FILE
                                                CONTROL
                                                STRATEGY
                                                MODEL
                                                                POINT
                                                            SOURCE CONTROL
                                                                COSTS
 REGIONAL
AIR QUALITY
  DISPLAY
                                     I	
I	_«_._____	___—_.
                   Figure 6-1.  Implementation Planning Program
                                       56

-------
       Before regional emission control  strategies  are  tested,  a  Control
 Cost File is prepared by the computer.   Each major source  (i.e.,  point
 source) is assigned all control devices which may  reasonably be  used  for
 reducing emissions from that source.  For  particulate  emissions,  control
 devices generally take the form of  emission control equipment  applied
 externally to the polluting process.  For  sulfur dioxide emission,  either
 low sulfur fuel substitutions or flue gas  desulfurization  techniques
 are entered into the file.   The Control Cost File  thus takes the form of
 a list of all point sources and the appropriate control devices  for each
 source, with each alternative device representing  a different  level of
 control efficiency for a given source.
       The  IPP model  is used  to  evaluate the'effectiveness of alternative
control  strategies  for a region.  A control strategy is a combination of
emission control  standards for  specific categories of emission sources.
Different  emission  standards are normally applied  to three major source
categories:  solid waste disposal, industrial processes, and fuel com-
bustion.   An additional emission standard uniformly reduces the emissions
from area  sources by a specified amount.
       When-the effectiveness of a control strategy is analyzed, the Control
Strategy Model applies the designated emission standards to each of the
point  sources in  the AQCR.  The reduction in emissions from point sources
                                                              •
generally  lowers  the pollutant concentrations  within the region.   The Con-
trol Strategy Model recomputes the pollution concentration distribution
and calculates the emission control costs for  sources affected  by the
emission standards.  The most significant output of the Control Strategy
Model  is 'a regional display of pollutant concentrations and an  estimate  of
the annual control cost for all sources  in the region which mus-t  comply
with the control strategy.
       The  IPP model is now be.ing used by APCO to evaluate emission control
strategies in implementation plans.   TRW has utilized the IPP model in
evaluating emission standards for the District of Columbia portion of  the
National Capital  Interstate Air Quality  Control Region (NCIAQCR)  and the
model  implementation plan for the Metropolitan  Cincinnati  Interstate Air
                                     57

-------
 Quality  Control  Region  (MCIAQCR).  The use of the IPP model in evaluating
 the  effectiveness  of alternative particulate control strategies in the
 NCIAQCR  is  briefly described  in  the following paragraphs.
       Figure  6-2 illustrates  the existing ground-level particulate concen-
 trations in the  NCIAQCR as  predicted by the calibrated Atmospheric
 Diffusion Model.   In this region,  the goal_ of the implementation plan
 was  to attain  an annual arithmetic average of particulate concentrations
            f                                     o
 of 86.6  yg/m-*  as an interim standard and 65.2 yg/m  as a long-term standard.
 In testing  the acceptability  of  a  strategy, the IPP model is used to
 ascertain the  annual average  concentration does not exceed the"long-term
 air  quality standard at any point  in the AQCR.
      To meet  the above standards,  a control strategy  for reduction  of the
particulate concentration was required.   The isopleths in Figure  6-2
                                                         3
indicate that  annual average concentrations  above  90 yg/m were observed
                                                   o
in the NCIAQCR.  Concentrations of  up to 107.7  yg/m  could be  expected
                   3                       3
within this 90 yg/m  isopleth (the  100 yg/m   isopleth  was too  small  to be
drawn on the map).   Analytical results for  10 control  strategies  are
presented in Table 6-1.   The reduction in emissions  from  point and area
sources is indicated,  as well as the control cost  expected and the pollutant
concentrations at the  maximum receptor in the region.   Strategy 18 was
selected for the District of Columbia,  on the basis  of (1) control costs,
(2)  expected air quality (which, within experimental error,  approximated
the air quality standard),  and (3)  the assumption  that the emission  control
technologies required  to meet the strategy were technically  feasible and
economically reasonable.  Particulate levels expected  after  the application
of the proposed control strategy are illustrated in  Figure 6-3.
      In summary, the  IPP model is  a tool which measures  the effectiveness
of alternative control strategies.   The display of expected  air quality
is the most valuable evaluation criterion available  for resource  decision-
making.  The calculated control costs represent only an estimate  of  the
direct cost of emission control to  the major point sources,  however,  and
have not been  utilized in economic  analyses.   Costs  have  thus  had only a
general effect on air  resource decision-making.
                                     58

-------
NOTE:  Annual Concentration In vg/"»
  Figure 6-2.   Existing  Ground  Level  Particulate  Concentrations  in  the
               NCIAQCR as  Computed  by the  Verified  Diffusion Model
                                     59

-------
0\
o
                                                      TABLE 6-1


             PARTICULATE CONTROL STRATEGIES - NATIONAL CAPITAL INTERSTATE AIR QUALITY CONTROL REGION



                      POINT SOURCES                 ^AREA SOURCES                CONTROL COST
Strategy
Number

1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
18
**
Percent
Reduction

36.3
87. A
62.2
52.7
86.4
78.2
76.0
36.3
41.0
77.0
70.4

New Emission Rate
(tons/day)
(84.7)**
54.0
10.7
32.0
40.1
11.6
18.4
19.9
54.0
50.0
19.5
25.0

Percent
Reduction

18.0
51.4
47.5
48.6
51.4
51.4
51.4
36.3
18.6
51.4
51.4

New Emission Rate
(tons/day)
(75.6)**
62. .0
36.7
39.7
38.9
36.7
36.7
36.7
48.2
61.6
36.7
36.7

$ x 106

0.5
13.9
4.0
4.4
11.8
11.6
11.6
0.5
0.6
11.6
10.8

$/ton removed

47
514
210
267
471
489
489
47
44
489
498

Maximum
Receptor
(pg/m3)

107.7
92.2
90.0
76.0
69.4
69.7
69.7
89.8
81.8
70.0
68.2

        Existing  conditions based on the 1969 inventory collected for the NCIAQCR and the validated

        diffusion model.

-------

v
                               x
y   • v
                                                                  \
Note:  Annual Concentrations In
   Figure 6-3.
 Predicted Particulate Concentrations After the Enactment
 of the Proposed Emission Control Strategy in all
 Political Jurisdictions
                                    61

-------
6.2  POINT SOURCE CONTROL COSTS
       The IPP modal computes the expected emission control costs for both
public and private point sources.  Control technologies are hypothetically
applied to point sources as a basis for the cost-estimating procedures.
These costs are generally acceptable for cross-sectional C/B analyses.
For greater accuracy, some fuel prices and control technique assumptions
should be upgraded, since the costs are based on 1967 data.
6.3  AREA SOURCE CONTROL COSTS
       Emission sources in an AQCR that are not considered point sources
are represented in the IPP model as area sources.  The area source cate-
gory includes residential and small commercial fuel combustion, residential
and commercial solid waste', automobiles, and process sources not large
enough to be identified as a point source.  Area sources are not identified
individually in.the IPP model, and emission control cost estimates are not
prepared for these sources.
       The task of identifying control techniques and control costs for
area sources has not been a high-priority item under the present RAPA con-
tract because of other priorities.  As cost/benefit analysis techniques
are developed, however, greater emphasis must be placed on determining
rigorous cost estimates for all important sources.   The resources invested
in such cost estimates must, of course, be weighed against the benefits
derived.  Since cost estimates for point sources alone are inadequate for
regional C/B evaluations, it appears the expenditure of resources in
developing a cost-estimating procedure for area sources is justifiable.
       No set procedure was developed during this study for determining
area source control costs.   The following guidelines were defined, however,
as a basis for future research:
           •   A uniform reduction in area source emissions
               throughout a region will affect individual
               jurisdictions differently because of differences
               in density and the mix of sources.  Area source
               cost functions should thus be developed on a
 For a full description of the control cost estimating procedure,  see TRW
Systems Group, Air Quality Implementation Planning Program - Volume I,
Operators Manual, Contract No. PH 22-68-60, November 1970.

                                    62

-------
               census tract or grid basis so that cost
               functions can be related to characteristics
               of the local community or neighborhood.

           •   Crude linear approximations of area source
               control cost functions may be sufficiently
               sensitive for the model (the function being
               determined by only one or two cost-effectiveness
               data points and the origin).  The functions may
               be based on census tract or other data and
               economic data from the Economics of Clean Air
               Report.1  The following relationships may be
               developed:

               •   Residual heating control costs, based on
                   number and size of households per census
                   tract.
               •   Auto exhaust control costs, based on number
                   of automobile miles travelled.
               •   Solid waste disposal control costs, based
                   on population per census tract.

6.4  CONTROL AGENCY COSTS

      Another cost category which must be  evaluated  in a C/B analysis is

 the cost associated with  implementation of  the control program by the

 public sector.   For purposes of  the  analysis, control agency costs can be
 taken as an allocation of  the control agency budget  for all jurisdictions

 in an AQCR for control of  the specific pollutants under analysis.  In
 evaluating the cost of a  specific control  strategy,  the relevant control
 agency costs are the incremental costs determined from the budget required
 for the current  level of  effort  and  the budget required to support the
 agency under the proposed  control strategy.  Figure  6-4 shows the format

 used for reporting control agency costs in  the NCIAQCR.

      Most of the current  air pollution control  legislation is based on the
 concept of controlling pollutant emissions  th-rough direct regulation (in
 the form of an emission  standard).  The Tax Reform Act of 1969, on the
 other hand, includes inducements in  the form of  a provision for a 5-year
1
 U.  S.  Senate, The Economics of Clean Air,  Third  Report  of  the Administrator
of the Environmental Protection Agency to  the Congress of  the  United  States,
U. S.  Government Printing Office,  Washington, D.  C.,  January 1971

                                     63

-------
JURISDICTION
POLLUTANTS
MARYLAND
• MONTGOMERY CTY.
• P. GEORGES CTY.
STATE OF VIRGINIA
• ARLINGTON CTY.
• FAIRFAX CTY.
• LOUDOUN CTY.
• PRINCE WILLIAM CTY.
• ALEXANDRIA CITY
• FAIRFAX CITY
• FALLS CHURCH
DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA

TOTAL '
1970 BUDGET*
(S)
TOTAL











sox &
PART.











BUDGET FOR
COMPLIANCE**
(S)
TOTAL











SOX &
PART.











**
 CURRENT  "LEVEL OF  EFFORT."

'BUDGET NEEDED TO SUPPORT AIR  RESOURCE PROGRAM FOR AN IDENTIFIED
 CONTROL  STRATEGY.
            Figure 6-4 .  Accounting for Control Agency Costs
                                    64

-------
write-off on pollution control equipment installed in industrial plants
which were  in operation on December 31, 1968.  Some states have likewise
recognized  the need for and desirability of some form of mechanism to help
companies absorb  the heavy initial control costs. - Such relief generally
takes one of three forms.  The purchaser of control equipment may be allowed
to accelerate the depreciation write-off (over a period of 1 to 5 years)
for income tax or franchise tax purposes.   Purchases of  pollution abate-
ment equipment may be exempted from sales  and use taxes,  or pollution
abatement installations may be exempted from property taxes.
      In cost/benefit analysis,  it is  important to include the  social
costs to the public sector which result from financial incentives,  credit
subsidies, and other inducements for private sector emission control.
When air pollution control strategies  in a  region are based on  direct
regulation,  the social cost of the inducement  is  not  substantial  (but
should nonetheless be evaluated).   When tax write-offs, direct  payments,
and other forms of financial inducements are utilized, the social  cost  to
the public sector is substantial.   More intensive study of such schemes
is recommended.
                                    65

-------
                            7.0  BENEFIT MODEL

      The social costs of air pollution control include all economic
effects resulting from the allocation of resources to administration,
research, enforcement, measurement, and implementation in connection
with the control of pollutant emissions.  Social benefits, on the other
hand, are those increases in welfare which result from improved air
quality.  To measure the benefits resulting from the application of control
strategies, a Benefit Model has been developed (see Figure 7-1).  The
Benefit Model determines damage costs by relating air quality data to
receptor data and to damage functions which express the social value of
air quality data to receptor data and to damage functions which express
the social value of air quality effects on receptors.  The difference in
air pollution damage cost between existing air quality and the control
strategy air quality is the value of the strategy "benefit."
      The control supplier function, also shown in Figure 7-1, is a
relationship (not yet developed) which predicts the stimulus to the
             *
regional economy resulting from the demand for air pollution control
equipment and services.  Benefits to control equipment suppliers are an
important input in regional econometric modeling and, although not part
of the present contract, have definite economic significant and are
                                                       i
briefly discussed in Appendix D.
      To put the Benefit Model in perspective, a flow diagram of a cross-
sectional C/B model (without the Control Supplier Function) is presented
in Figure 7-2.  As illustrated, control strategy air quality is first re-
lated to receptor information (census tract data).   Damage is determined
for each Census tract by means of a damage function which expresses damage
cost as a function of air quality and census data.   The regional damage
cost is computed by summing overall census tracts in the  AQCR.
      The design of the Benefit Model is described in the following
sections.
7.1  RECEPTOR DATA
      In cost/benefit analysis, the consequences of government policies
are traced back to the fulfillment of individual (or household) wants.
                                                PRECEDING PAGE BLANK

-------
                  IMPLEMENTATION
                  PLANNING
                  PROGRAM
              STRATEGY AIR QUALITY AT
              250"RECEPTOR POINTS
RECEPTOR
  DATA'
 CONTROL
 SUPPLIER
 FUNCTION
                       1
                     BENEFIT
                     MODEL
T
BENEFITS
PER CAPITA,
PER CENSUS TRACT,
OR FOR THE AIR
QUALITY CONTROL
REGION
                   DAMAGE
                   FUNCTIONS
         Figure  7-1.   Benefit Model Design
                         68

-------
AREA
SOURCE
CONTROL
COSTS
                                                        IPP
                                                     CONTROL
                                                     STRATEGY
                                                     MODEL
                                                     STRATEGY AIR QUALITY
POINT
SOURCE
CONTROL
COSTS
CONTROL
AGENCY
COSTS
                 REGIONAL
                 CONTROL
                   COSTS
CENSUS TRACT INTERFACE
(CTAQ).
                                           DAMAGE FUNCTION RELATIONSHIP
                                           •(CTDC). = [o+b(CTAQ)J (CTP).
                                    REGIONAL^
                                  DAMAGE COST'
                                 RDC •=» 2 (CTDC).
                                   ALL CENSUS
                                     TRACTS
                                 o = DAMAGE FUNCTION INTERCEPT ($/CAPITA)

                                 b =• DAMAGE FUNCTION SLOPE ($/Mg/m3/CAPITA)
             WHERE:'
   (CTAQ). = CENSUS TRACT AIR QUALITY

          = AIR QUALITY FOR RECEPTOR NUMBER, j

           DAMAGE COST FOR CENSUS TRACT, t ($)
                     (AQ.)

                     (CTDC).
                     (CTP).  = POPULATION FOR CENSUS TRACT, i

                     RDC   = DAMAGE COST FOR REGION ($)

                     •EXAMPLE OF SIMPLE LINEAR DAMAGE FUNCTION
    Figure 7-2.  Cross-Sectional Cost-Benefit Model  for  Given Pollutant and Damage  Function

-------
Tliis  rule of  cost/benefit  analysis was  the determining  factor in  the

selection of  census  tract  information to describe air pollutant receptors

at  this  time  (additional data descriptive of receptors may be added at

some  later  time).  In addition  to obtaining extensive information on the

population  of  a  region, the  Bureau of the Census tabulates significant

information on individual  and household characteristics.  The Department

of  Commerce defines  census tracts as follows:

       "Census  tracts are small, permanently established,
       geographical areas into which large cities and their
       environs have  been divided for statistical purposes.
       Tract boundaries are selected by  local committee and .
       approved by the Bureau of the Census.  They remain the
       same  for a long time so that statistical comparisons
       can be made from year  to  year and from census to census,
       The average tract has  over 4,000 people and is originally
       laid  out with  attention to achieving some uniformity of
       of population  characteristics, economic status, and living
       conditions.  In each decennial census, the Bureau of the
       Census  tabulates population and housing information for
       each  tract—hence, the name "census tract".."1

      It is important to know the criteria used in defining census tracts.

The Census Bureau has found that certain definitive criteria  should be

applied in order to make the tract statistics useful to as many interests

as possible and  to facilitate enumeration.  These standards limit the
populations, specify the best types of  boundaries,  and  indicate the type

of homogeniety needed.   The criteria* are as follows:

            •  Population  Size -i Census tract should contain  between
               2500 and 8000 inhabitants, but may contain somewhat more.
               Tracts covering a large population are desirable if
               the population is homogeneous.  The average size for all
               tracts should not be less than 4000.

            •  Boundaries  - Census tract boundaries should follow
               permanent and easily recognized lines (state lines,
  U.S. Department of Commerce, Census Tract Manual, Washington, D.C.,
  U.S. Government Printing Office, p. 1, January 1966.
*
 These descriptions have been condensed from the Census Tract Manual
 (Ibid) pp. 32-38.
                                     70

-------
               highways, railroads, rivers, streams, channels, and the
               like).  Alleys are normally not used and should not be
               unless named.
            •  Homogeniety - Census tracts should contain, insofar as is
               practicable, persons of similar racial or nationality
               characteristics, of similar economic status, and of
               similar housing.  If a tract includes both expensive homes
               and slum dwellings, for example, average statistics for
               the tract as a whole will not reflect the condition of
               either group.
            •  Geographic Shape and Size - In general, a census tract
               should be compact.  It is desirable to avoid panhandles,
               L's, dumbbells, and other elongated shapes.  Irregular
               boundaries should be avoided wherever possible.
      As part  of  this  effort,  a procedure was developed  for relating
air quality data (as calculated by the Atmospheric Diffusion Model) to
census tracts.  The Atmospheric Diffusion Model is currently designed to
compute air pollutant concentrations at approximately 250 receptor points
(located on a grid) within an AQCR.  Figure 7-3 shows the relationship
between receptor points and census tracts for the Washington, D. C.
Standard Metropolitan Statistical Area (SMSA).   The procedure  uses the
existing receptor grid and census tract data, since reorienting the
receptor grid to the centroid of each census tract  would have been
costly initially and would have likewise led to increases in operational
computer time.  Instead, an analytical procedure was developed to form the
interface.  This procedure will be described in detail in the follow-on
report.  Briefly, the procedure involves the selection of specific receptor
points to represent each census tract.  This operation is conducted once
for each AQCR by a researcher before the regional analysis, is begun.   Each
census tract is identified by one or more receptor points which represent
that tract (see Figure 7-4).  The computer then calculates a  simple arith-
metic average of the pollutant concentrations at the receptor points.
This average is referred to as the "census tract air quality" (CTAQ).
7.2  DAMAGE FUNCTIONS
      Damage functions are the most complicated and least clearly defined
inputs to the Benefit Model, owing to the lack of knowledge of the cause-
and-effect relationship between air pollutants  and receptors  and the
current inability to place a value on the effects.
                                     71

-------
                                 CFNSI'S TK-vns is •nre vwsitiNr.
.XX
    Location of receptor point  and receptor point number,  XX.
        Figure 7-3a.   Receptor Points Superimposed  on Census Tracts
                       of the NCIAQCR (Macroscopic view)
                                    72

-------
Figure 7-3b.  Receptor Points Superimposed on Census Tracts
              of the NC1AQCR  (Microscopic view)
                           :-' <

-------
INPUTS
RECEPTOR
NUMBER
045
067
163
AIR QUALITY (ng/m3)
PART.
73.6
72.5
70.1
S0x
52.1
54.3
50.5
                                                                     CENSUS
                                                                     TRACT
                                                                     NUMBER
                                                                     C109502
                                                   RECEPTOR POINTS
                                                   REPRESENTING
                                                   CENSUS TRACT
                                                   045,  067,  163
OUTPUTS
CENSUS
TRACT
NUMBER
                                   0109502
                                                   AIR QUALITY (wg/nr)
                                                    PART.
                 72.1
                                 SO
52.3
                         Figure 7-4  .  Receptor Point - Census Tract Interface

-------
      In the following subsections, some of the characteristics of damage
functions, are described and problems associated with their measurement
are noted.  The literature contains little information on the development
of air pollution damage functions, but references are cited whenever
possible.
7.2.1  Description of a Damage Function
      In an economic sense, supply and demand exist for air quality just
as they do for goods and services in the private sector.  In the privat.e
sector, price is a function of the effects of supply and demand for goods
and services in the marketplace.   Since there is no marketplace for the
air resource, the price of clean air will depend upon society's willingness
to pay for improved air quality.   Figure 7-5 illustrates a conceptual
supply-demand relationship for air quality.
       In Figure  7-6,  a  parallel  is  drawn between the demand for goods
and services in the private sector and that for 'a,ir quality in the public
sector.  An air pollution damage function is in essence a demand function
for air quality, an aggregation of the citizens' willingness to pay for a
collective good.  Willingness to pay for air quality' is the damage func-
tion expression that  is applicable to cost/benefit modeling.  Individuals
may pay to avoid such damages as corrosion of materials and soiling of
property for example.  Many people likewise prefer to avoid intangible
air pollution effects which are detrimental to aesthetic pleasure or which
produce general sluggishness.
      In cost/benefit analysis, the consequences of government actions
are all traced back to the.fulfillment of wants of individuals.  Indivi-
duals feel the effects of air pollution directly and indirectly in the
form of:
            •  Actual outlays,
            •  Reduction in his income, health or satisfaction, or
            •  Complete foreclosure of some opportunities.
      In practical terms, a damage function represents a dose-response
relationship in which the damage cost is the price an individual (or
individuals) will pay to avoid the response.  Damage functions are

-------
a:
O.
                       AIR QUALITY
SUPPLY  = MARGINAL CONTROL COST

DEMAND  = MARGINAL BENEFITS
    Figure 7-5 .  Supply - Demand Relationship for Air Quality
                             76

-------
   'DEMAND FUNCTIONS CAN BE DETERMINED FOR GOODS AND SERVICES  IN
   THE MARKETPLACE, THAT IS  ...
   t
PRICE
                                   QUANTITY
   'A DAMAGE FUNCTION MAY BE CONSIDERED AN AIR QUALITY DEMAND FUNCTION,
   THAT IS, A "WILLINGNESS TO PAY" FOR QUALITY OF THE AIR'RESOURCE
   (AS COMPARED TO QUANTITY OF PRODUCT) ...
   t
PRICE*
                               AIR QUALITY
*THE PRICE ONE IS WILLING TO PAY TO HAVE IMPROVED AIR QUALITY
                  Figure  7-6.    What  is  a  Damage  Function?

-------
expressed in the form of a rate (i.e.,  value of damage allocated over a
fixed period of time).  Figure 7-7 shows the variables used in measuring
the rate of damage.  The valuation of damage is expressed as the cost
factor K.
7.2.2  Identification of Air Pollution Effects
      The social benefits associated with improved air quality and the
economic concepts used to describe these effects are discussed in
Appendix A. in this section, attention is focused on the identification
and classification of effects for the practical purpose of developing
benefit estimates.  It is hoped that the material presented here'will
stimulate the development of methods of classifying air pollution effects
and will aid in the structuring of research on effects and damage functions.
      Air pollution effects may be categorized as follows:
            •  Direct Effects - The direct and immediate externalities
               borne by the receptor.
            •  Adjustments  (Indirect Effects) - Effects which induce
               persons and  firms to make certain adjustments in order
               to  reduce the direct impact of the pollutant.
            •  Market Effects - Effects realized through the marketplace
               as a result of adjustments made to reduce the direct
               impact of pollutant concentrations. 1
      Air pollution effects are felt by the individual, the corporate
sector, and the public sector.   (See Figure 7-8).  As may be seen from
the figure, effects realized by the corporate sector are passed along to
the consumer in the form of price increases.  The effects of air pollution
on the public sector are likewise usually passed along to the taxpayer in
the form of increased taxes.  Figure 7-9 gives examples of effects on the
individual, the private sector, and the public sector.  -Benefits to the indivi-
dual are divided as follows:
  Ridker, Ronald G.,   Economic Costs of Air Pollution - Studies in Measure-
  ment , Frederick A.  Praeger, New York, p.  14, 1967.
                                     78

-------
        A
   DAMAGE
   COST PER
   YEAR ($/YR)
                            POLLUTION CONCENTRATION
                               (AIR QUALITY	-)
                RATE OF DAMAGE
where:
 where:
         D = f[ a, t, AQ,  RC,  PP ]
D = Damage per period of exposure.
a = Concomitant conditions,  such as temperature,  pressure,  humidity,  etc,
t = Exposure duration(ie, 1  year)
AQ = Pollutant concentration
RC =•Receptor characteristics
PP = Properties of pollutant

      ANNUAL  DAMAGE  COST
                   •
 C  =  (K)(D)  = g [ K, a, t, AQ, RC,  PP  ]

 K =  Cost  per  unit damage
 C - Damage cost per period  of  exposure

            Figure  7-7.   Damage  Function - A Rate

-------
                                              ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF AIR POLLUTION
                                       COST OF POLLUTION
                                                     COST OF POLLUTION CONTROL
               [WNERSHIP

           EFFECTS
INDIVIDUAL
CORPORATE
PUBLIC
INDIVIDUAL
CORPORATE
                                                                             PUBLIC
             DIRECT
            ADJUSTMENTS
             MARKET
oo
O
                            INDIVIDUAL
                            OR
                            HOUSEHOLD
                            WELFARE
                                            MARKET
                                            PRICES
                                TAXES
                                             INDIVIDUAL
                                             OR
                                             HOUSEHOLD
                                             WELFARE
                                               MARKET
                                               PRICES
                                                                              TAXES
                           Figure  7-8.    Structuring the Economic Effects of Air  Pollution

-------
SOCIAL BENEFITS = Bt  =  Bh + B  + B.  + BU

WHERE:
   Bh = INDIVIDUAL HEALTH BENEFITS
    n    •  INCREASED NET AGGREGATE PRODUCTIVITY  BENEFITS  FROM ENHANCED:
             •JOB PERFORMANCE
             •PRODUCTIVE LIFE SPAN
             •ALERTNESS, PSYCHOLOGICAL SATISFACTION,  ETC.

         •  INCREASED NET AGGREGATE CONSUMPTION BENEFITS  FROM  REDUCED:
             •MEDICAL CARE
             • PREVENTIVE MEDICINE, ETC.

   B  = INDIVIDUAL PROPERTY BENEFITS
    p    •  INCREASED NET AGGREGATE PRODUCTIVITY  BENEFITS  FROM PROPERTY,  I.E.,
            • MATERIALS
            • ANIMALS
            • VEGETATION
            • LAND, ETC.

        •  INCREASED NET AGGREGATE CONSUMPTION BENEFITS  FROM  REDUCED
           PROPERTY MAINTENANCE,  I.E.,
          .  • LAUNDRY
            • AUTO WASHING
            • WINDOW CLEANING,  ETC.

   B. = PRIVATE SECTOR BENEFITS
    1      •  NET AGGREGATE PRODUCTIVITY  BENEFITS OF  GOODS  AND SERVICES
              PURCHASED FROM THE  PRIVATE  SECTOR  RESULTING  FROM PRICES
              WHICH DO NOT INCLUDE THE COST  (TO  THE FIRM) OF:
               • CLEANLINESS
               • PROPERTY DISUTILITY
               '• INCREASED WORKER PRODUCTIVITY,  ETC.

   B  = PUBLIC SECTOR BENEFITS
    u   •   NET AGGREGATE PRODUCTIVITY  BENEFITS OF PUBLIC SECTOR SERVICES
           DUE TO COSTS TO THE  GOVERNMENTS FOR:
            • CLEANLINESS
            • PROPERTY DISUTILITY
            • INCREASED WORKER  PRODUCTIVITY,  ETC.
    Figure  7-9.    Social  Benefits  Resulting  from Air Pollution Control


                                     81

-------
            9  Effects relating to'the individual's person (i.e., health,
               welfare, productivity etc.).
            •  Effects relating to property owned by the individual.
      Information on air pollution effects can be found in APCO's criteria
documents for specific pollutants,* which contain comprehensive reviews
of specific pollutant effects as well as extensive bibliographies.
7.2.3  Assessment of Air Pollution Effects
      Once the effects have been identified, the next step in developing
damage functions is to assess the magnitude of. these effects.  This proce-
dure will require an analysis of the chemical reactions between pollutants
and receptors, as well as a determination of the physiological, pathological,
psychological, and other effects of the pollutants on living organisms.
The dose-response relationship between pollutant and receptor must also
be examined.  As is indicated in the criteria documents, the analyst must
be concerned with the following factors:
            •  Concentration
            •  Chemical composition
            •  Mineralogical structure
            •  Absorbed gases
            •  Co-existing pollutants
            •  Physical state of pollutant
                      •  Solid
                      •  Liquid
                      •  Gaseous
      In addition, the characteristics of the receptor must be evaluated.
Relevant characteristics include:
1 RAPA model evaluates particulate and sulfur dioxide emission.   Criteria
  documents for these pollutants are:  Air Quality Criteria for  Particulate
  Matter (AP-49) and Air Quality Criteria for Sulfur Oxides (AP-50).  U.S.
  DREW, NAPCA, Washington, D. C., January 1969.
2 Ibid. p.  XIV.

                                    82

-------
            •  Physical characteristics
            •  Individual susceptibility
            •  State of health
            •  Rate and sight of transfer of receptor
      The measurement of pollution effects is greatly complicated by the
fact that such effects are quite subtle and vary according to both pollutant
concentration and duration of exposure.   Degree of exposure is expressed
in terms of dosage (duration of exposure times pollution concentration).
Because of changing atmospheric conditions the pollutant concentration to
which an Individual is exposed varies significantly over a relatively short
period of time.  In addition, there are numerous pollutants which affect
receptors, and the aggregate mix of pollutants at any one location is
constantly changing.   As human beings move from place to place in the course
of a day, they are exposed to an even greater variety of combinations of
pollutants.  Finally, the effects of pollutants on health and property re-
main unclear owing to the lack of a full understanding of synergistic
phenomena.  Much additional research is needed if the total effects of air
pollution are to be determined.
7.2.4  Evaluation of Air Pollution Effects
      The third and final task in the process of producing a damage
function is an evaluation of the effects which have been identified and
assessed.  Problems arise, of course,  in placing a price on effects such
as those outlined above.  Welfare economists consider the value of social
benefits to be a function of the individual's personal preference for the
benefits (i.e., the individual's.willingness to pay).  In preparing damage
functions, the analyst is faced with such complex problems as determining
society's willingness to pay when society itself is unable to clearly
identify the effects  of air pollution, or attempting to determine the value
which society places  on one of a number of synergistic effects resulting
from air pollution, cigarette smoking, natural oxidation, etc.  The need  to
evaluate the aesthetic consequences of air pollution further complicates
matters, since such effects are perceived by the individual, on both the
conscious and subconscious levels.

-------
      The. task of evaluating public undertakings involves  working in the
absence of market prices for most analytical inputs and outputs.   The
job of the analyst is to develop values for inputs and outputs which are
consistent with those found in the marketplace.
      The pries placed on a public good is referred to as  a "shadow price."
Shadow pricing has been discussed in some detail by Margolis* and McKean.**
Margolis states that  "the process of forming the shadow values is made
difficult not only because of market limitations, but also because there
is no widespread agreement on the basis for generating social values.
Should one try to aggregate the preference of people in a  society or
should one attempt to rely on the preferences of program planners or
adminstrators?"***  Margolis also argues that it is the willingness to
pay for government outputs which signifies their values.
      The purpose of evaluating air pollution costs and benefits is to
assist the decision-maker in determining a policy.  Shadow prices are
utilized so that the effects of a public program (as it affects society)
can be evaluated in monetary terms  (i.e., on the basis of  a common unit
for comparing effects).  Shadow prices are useful means of expressing
utility, but unless the decision-maker is confident of the monetary values
assigned to the effects, little is gained through the analytical process.
      The question of how shadow prices are determined is, of course,
highly relevant.  Margolis discusses techniques for estimating "willingness
to pay."***  Figure 7-10 summarizes the shadow pricing program and identi-
fies  three methods of determining shadow prices.  The various literature on
the analysis of public expenditures contains theoretical discussions of
this  topic.
    J.  Margolis,  "Shadow Prices  for  Incorrect  or  Nonexistent Market Values,"
    in  Joint  Economic  Committee,  U.S.  Congress, The Analysis and  Evaluation
    of  Public Expenditure;   The  PPB  System, Vol.  I, U.S. Government Printing
    Office,  pp.  533-546, 1969.
  **R.  N.  McKean,  "The Use  of  Shadow Prices,"  in  S. B. Chase, Jr. ed.,
    Problems  in  Public Expenditure Analysis, The  Brookings  Institution,
    Washington,  D.  C.  pp 33-77,  1968.
 ***J.  Margolis,  op.  cit.,  pp.  541-546.
                                     84

-------
 • WHY IS THERE A VALUATION PROBLEM? 	 BECAUSE THERE IS NO
   MARKET WHERE SUPPLY AND DEMAND FOR THIS PRODUCT (THAT IS,
   QUALITY AIR) DETERMINES A PRICE
   HOW THEN IS A PRICE PLACED ON SUCH A PUBLIC GOOD?
   MEASUREMENT RULE USED IS AS FOLLOWS:
THE
         ESTIMATE WHAT THE USERS OF THE PUBLIC PRODUCT ARE WILLING
         TO PAY 	 SUCH A MEASUREMENT IS CALLED A "SHADOW PRICE"
 • HOW ARE SHADOW PRICES DETERMINED?
METHOD #1  CONSIDER THE PRODUCT AS AN INTERMEDIATE GOOD AND THEN
           ESTIMATE THE VALUE OF THE MARGINAL PRODUCT OF THE GOOD
           IN FURTHER PRODUCTION, THAT IS, ASSUME THE USER IS A
           PRODUCER AND THEN ASK:  BY HOW MUCH DOES THE PUBLIC
           OUTPUT INCREASE HIS INCOME?
METHOD n  MEASURE THE COST SAVINGS OF THE PUBLIC SERVICE,  THAT
           IS, THE REDUCTION IN THE COSTS THAT THE INDIVIDUAL
           WOULD HAVE INCURRED IF THE PUBLIC SERVICE WERE NOT
           SUPPLIED.
METHOD #3  ESTIMATE DIRECTLY THE USERS PRICES BY APPEAL  TO MARKET
           INFORMATION, THAT IS, LOOK FOR NEAR SUBSTITUTES FOR
           COLLECTIVE CONSUMPTION.
          Figure 7-10.   How to Value  Air  Pollution  Effects?
                                 85

-------
 7.2.5  Types of Air Pollution Damage Functions
       Although there have been various attempts at determining air pollu-
 tion damage functions, this section will concentrate upon two examples,
 a damage function which valuates the direct effect of particulate soiling,
 and an analysis in which residential property values are estimated as a
 function of sulfur dioxide and particulate concentrations.
       The damage function developed by Wilson and Minnottee*  for the
 Washington, D. C., metropolitan area is presented in Figure 7-11.  The
 damage function relates per capita annual soiling cost to concentrations
 of suspended particulates.  The authors utilized the results of air pollu-
 tion statistical studies in the Washington, D. C., area conducted by
 Irving Michelson.  Michelson's study used responses to a questionnaire to
 determine the frequency of certain household cleaning chores Ln areas  of high
 and low air pollution within the metropolitan area.** Wilson and Minnottee
 applied shadow prices to the "frequency of cleaning" function determined
 by Michelson.  Method //3 (Figure 7-10) Wfls utilized, that is the prices of
 cleaning services in the private sector were determined and then applied
 to the specific chores identified by Michelson.  The soili'ng damage func-
 tion was'utilized to estimate savings (benefits) from reduced soiling for
 residential households.'  Studies of a similar nature have been conducted
 in Kansas City, and the Ironton-Ashland-Huntington metropolitan area.  The
 procedures used in developing the damage functions were those previously
 outlined in this section (identification, assessment, and evaluation).
       In the basis of a statistical analysis, economists Robert J. Anderson,
 Jr., and Thomas D. Crocker have determined a negative correlation between
 particulate and sulfur dioxide concentrations and residential property
 values.*** The authors evaluated the combined effects of suspended
   R. D. Wilson and D. W. Minnottee, "A cost-Benefit Approach to Air
   Pollution Control", Journal of the Air Pollution Control Association,
   Vol. 19, No.5, p. 306, May 1969.
** I. Michelson, "The Household Cost of Living in Polluted Air in the  .
   Washington, D. C. Metropolitan Area", A Report to the U.S. Public Health
   Service.
***R. J. Anderson, Jr., and T. D. Crocker, "Air Pollution and Housing:
   Some Findings" Paper No. 264, Institute for Research in the Behavioral,
   Economics, and Management Sciences, Purdue University, Lafayette,
   Indiana, January 1970.
                                      86

-------
       160  -
O.

5

QC
UJ
O.
   .
O »-
o •-<
  0.
CD 
O



S*
 II
>-
       120
        80
        40 '
                                         Y =  1.85  X -  42
                       20          40            60          80          100


                     X = SUSPENDED PARTICULATE  CONCENTRATION '(ug/m3)
 Source:   Wilson and Minnotte
        Figure 7-11.  Example  Damage Function for Direct Effects

-------
^articulates and sulfur dioxide (as measured by sulfation) on residential
property in the following Census Bureau classifications:  (1)  owner-
oci-.upiecl; (2) renter-occupied, gross rent; and (3) renter-occupied, con-
tract rent.   The most significant independent variables which affect
property values were identified and are shown in Figure 7-12.  It should
be noted that sulfaction rate and suspended particulate concentration are
included as significant variables.  The statistical results of the Anderson
and Crocker work for the Washington, D. C., SMSA are presented in Table 7-1.
      The benefits measured by the Wilson/Minnotte and the Anderson/Crocker
damage functions represent only a small portion of the "benefits" that are
desired by society.  The Wilson/Minnotte function measures only the direct
effects of soiling resulting from suspended particulates.   Numerous other
direct effects have been identified for particulates as well as other pollu-
tants.  The Anderson/Crocker functions estimate only the market effects re-
sulting from society's preference to reside in cleaner rather than dirtier
air.  The market effects result from the conscious and subconscious per-
ception of direct effects.  The impact of the effects and  adjustments are
reflected in the values of properties as established in the marketplace.
      During this study, the Anderson/Crocker results for the Washington,
D. C., SMSA were examined to determine their potential as  a damage function
for estimating air pollution market effects.  The analytical results of the
Washington study will be tested as a predictive function in the demonstra-
tion of the C/B Model.
7.2.6  Application of Air Pollution Damage Functions
      Damage functions are generally expressed in relation to number of
households (or population) and pollution concentration.  In the Cost/Benefit
Model, damage functions are applied to each census tract in an AQCR to
determine the census tract damage cost.  The sum of the damage costs for all
census tracts in an AQCR determines the AQCR damage cost.
      The damage estimates of the direct effects of pollution are estimated
as a function of particulate and/or sulfur dioxide concentrations for the
base alternative (i.e., the existing condition) as well as for predicted
concentrations under a given emission control strategy.  Social benefit is
considered to be the difference between the damages from the base alterna-
tive and damages after application of the control strategy (see Figure 7-13.)
                                     88

-------
            PROPERTY VALUE FUNCTION:

            PV = f(a, PSN, PPT,  MFI,  DLP,  OLD,  NWT,  DIS,  MRM)
            WHERE PROPERTY .VALUE IS QUANTIFIED FOR EACH  CENSUS  TRACT  AS:

                  • TYPE I:     MEDIAN  PROPERTY VALUE  - OWNER-OCCUPIED
                  • TYPE II:    MEDIAN  PROPERTY VALUE  - OWNER-OCCUPIED -  75%  OR MORE  SINGLE  FAMILY DWELLINGS
                  • TYPE III:   MEDIAN  GROSS RENT  - RENTER-OCCUPIED
                  • TYPE IV:    MEDIAN  CONTRACT RENT - RENTER-OCCUPIED
CO
            THE INDEPENDENT VARIABLES OF SIGNIFICANCE  ARE  AS  FOLLOWS:
                    a    =  CONSTANT
                    PSN  =  ANNUAL ARITHMETIC MEAN SULFATION
                    PPT  =  ANNUAL ARITHMETIC MEAN SUSPENDED PARTICULATES
                    MFI  =  MEDIAN FAMILY INCOME
                    DLP  =  PERCENT OF LIVING UNITS DILAPIDATED
                    OLD  =  PERCENT OF HOUSES OVER TWENTY YEARS OLD IN 1959
                    NWT  =  PERCENT OF HOUSING OCCUPIED BY NONWHITES
                    DIS  =  DISTANCE OF CENSUS TRACT FROM CENTRAL BUSINESS DISTRICT
                    MRM  =  MEDIAN NUMBER OF ROOMS IN HOUSING UNIT
            *SEE TABLE 4-2 FOR QUANTITATIVE  RESULTS

            SOURCE:   ANDERSON AND CROCKER
                             Figure  7-12.   Example Damage  Function for Market Effect*

-------
                                               Table 7-1
              REGRESSION RESULTS OF ANDERSON-CROCKER STUDY FOR THE WASHINGTON,  D. C., SMSA
            DEPENDENT
Regression Coefficients
	
INDEPENDENT
Const.
In
In
In
In
In
In
In
In
R2
S2
T
(PSN)
(PPT)
(MFI)
(DLP)
(OLD)
(NWT)
(DIS)
(MRM)



"""""*——«. Type I
3.3901
-.0712 i
-.0610 i
.7677 i
.0044 i
-.016 l
.0251 i
-.0582 i

.6966
.0222
275
(.4012)
(.0222)
(.0318**)
(.0447)
(.0059**)
(.0103)
(.0064)
(.0158)




Type
1.1617
.0010
-.1698
.9970
.0113
-.0213
.0321
-.0312
.9064
.7897
.0179
121
(
(
(
(
(
(
(
(
(



II
.5622*)
.0270**)
.0509)
.0587)
.0079**)
.0107*)
.0080)
.0097)
.1948)



Type III
.2428
-.0905
.0049
.5109
.0121
-.0606
-.0043
-.0216

.6963
.0181
218
(.4441**)
(.0239)
(.0316**)
(.0492)
(.0055*)
(.0125)
(.0066**)
(.0152**)




Type
.4705
-.0727
-.0302
.4650
-.0054
• -.0408
-.0124
-.0111

.7549
.0136
218
(
(
(
(
(
(
(
(




IV
.3859**)
.0207)
.0275**)
.0431)
.0048**)
.0108)
.0058*)
.0132**)




 * Not significantly different from zero  at  the  .01  level.
** .Not significantly different from zero  at  the  .05  level.

-------
to   C
s
3   C
z
<
a:
o
LlJ
I/)
Q
UJ
tvl
                       DIRECT  EFFECTS

              POLLUTION CONCENTRATION  (yg/ni )
      C] =  (DAMAGE  COSTjPj;  C?  = (DAMAGE COST)P2
      SOCIAL BENEFIT  =  C]  -
                       MARKET EFFECTS
              POLLUTION CONCENTRATION  (u
       SOCIAL  BENEFIT = PV2 - PV1
      Figui-e 7-13.   Application of Damage  Functions

                            91

-------
T!K: social benefits from market efi'.ects are die differences between the
annualized household property values under the two strategies (also shown
in Figure 7-13).
       In  cross-sectional  cost/benefit  studies,  problems arise when air
 quality measurements  for  the  current year are not  representative of air
 quality  in  previous years (see Figure  7-14).   Air  quality may have improved
 as  a  result  of the implementation  of emission regulations, as is the case
 for sulfur  dioxide concentrations  in the  District  of Columbia (Figure  7-15).
 On  the other hand,  conditions may  have deteriorated.  Analytical problems
 arise because air  pollution  effects are not short-term phenomena,  but are
 rather a  function  of  historical air pollutant concentrations.  Air pollu-
 tion  effects such  as  soiling  are immediate effects and cleaning costs are
 a  function  of particulate concentrations  for  the base year.  Other effects,
 (such as  those on  health), result  from long-term exposure to pollutants
 and damage  functions  in these cases must  theoretically be determined on
 the basis of pollutant concentrations  calculated over a number of  years.
 Also, the reduction in damage cannot generally  be  assumed to be effective'
 instantaneously,, that is,  an  instantaneous reduction in pollutant  concen-
 tration does not bring about  an instantaneous improvement in human health
 or  productivity.   Although beyond  the  scope of  the present study,  such
 problems  must be examined in  future cost/benefit research.
                                    92

-------
o
t—«
1—

cc.
o
o.
o
>—1

o
LU
a:
         (AQ)
            el
        (AQ)


            (AQ)
                e2
        (AQ),
              1967
                          1968
1969
1970        1971



TIME (YEARS)
1972
1973
1974
1975
                        Figure  7-14.   Historical  Trends in Pollution Concentration

-------
                    GOVERNMENT OF THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA 'AIR  POLLUTION  DIVISION1
                                                                                                              286
                                           SULFUR REDUCED TO 1.0%
SULFUR REDUCED TO I.I
                                                                                     INTERIM AIR QUALITY COAL

                                                                                             I  I I  I
                                                                                     AIR QUALITY COAI
MAMJ  JASO NO
                 JFMAMJJASONO
                                     JFUAMJ JASOND
                                                         JFMAMJ JASOND
                                                                             JFMAMJ  J ASONO
                                                                                                  J F U A U J J
                                                       DATE

      Figure  7-15.   Monthly  Average Sulfur .Dioxide Concentrations  in the District of  Columbia

-------
 7.2.7  Development of Damage Functions
     There is a dire need for additional research on the effects of air
pollution.  As an interim measure, however, the development of methods
which transform available data into useful damage functions can be tested.
One of the advantages of a cost/benefit simulation tool is that it may be
used in sensitivity analyses to determine the reasonableness of proposed
damage functions.  Brain-storming sessions can be useful in determining
how the damage functions are to be created.  A modification of the Delphi
procedure may also be applicable as a means of estimating "personal
preferences."
     Many different approaches can be taken in the development of damage
functions.  The analyst may look at damages to individual classes of
receptors (pinto beans, electrical contacts, guinea pigs, etc.) and then
aggregate these damages by means of statistical techniques in order to
project total damage costs.  Another approach is to use analytical tech-
niques in the development of "comprehensive damage functions" based on
 the best available data  (see Figure 7-16).
     Many questions arise in evaluating methodologies for the development
of damage functions.  Must all effects be identified and evaluated, or
can knowledge of specific effects be the basis for decision-making?  Can
a comprehensive damage function be developed as a function of personal
income, residential location, occupation, health status, or other vari-
ables?  Can health data such as those obtained by Lave and Seskin (see
Table 7-2)  be used in the development of broad-based health functions?1
Can "personal preference" be defined on the basis of  intensive surveys and
congressional polls (i.e., do such polls indicate willingness to pay for
solutions to society's problems)?  How can sociologists, psychologists,
economists,  and statisticians contribute to a comprehensive study of
damage functions?
      Such questions must be examined  in relation to  the air resource
decision-making process and the needs  of the decision-maker.
  Lave, Lester B., and Seskin, Eugene P., "Air Pollution and Human Health,"
  jcience, 21 August 1970, Volume 169, Number 3947, pp. 724-734.

                                    95

-------
VO
               PER
               CAPITA
               COST

               ($)
                           BACKGROUND LEVEL
                           (THRESHOLD)
• INDIVIDUAL'S PROPERTY
                                                                       • INDIVIDUAL'S PERSON
                                                                       • PRIVATE SECTOR (REGIONAL)
                                                                       • PUBLIC SECTOR (REGIONAL)
                                                                       • PRIVATE SECTOR (OUTSIDE REGION)
                                                                       t PUBLIC SECTOR (OUTSIDE REGION)
                                    POLLUTION CONCENTRATION
                            Figure 7-16.  Comprehensive Damage Function for an AQCR

-------
                                 Table 7-2

                    EXAMPLE DATA FOR THE DEVELOPMENT OF
                    DAMAGE FUNCTIONS FOR HEALTH EFFECTS
                                POLLUTION             EXPECTED ANNUAL-
           DISEASE              REDUCTION           SAVING ($ MILLIONS)
•  All Respiratory Diseases        50%                     1,222

•  Cardiovascular Diseases         50%                       468

•  Cancer                          50%                       390


           TOTAL                                           2,080
   Source:   Lave and Seskin
                                    97

-------
               8.0  SOME APPLICATIONS OF THE COST/BENEFIT MODEL

      The Cost/Benefit Model will be service tested during the followon
efforts of this study.  The capabilities of the model will be tested
through numerous evaluations.  The present section reviews a few of the
model's capabilities.
      Economic evaluations of regional air pollution control strategies
should focus on the efficiency and distribution of costs and benefits to
society.  Measures of economic efficiency indicate the effectiveness of a
policy which requires a reallocation of resources.  Equity studies evaluate
the distribution of effects relative to various income groups.  The desired
goal relative to the equity criteria in the fair distribution of benefits
and costs to all sectors of a given population (e.g., an AQCR).
      To illustrate the flexibility and capabilities of the C/B Model,
this chapter presents a discussion on a collection of alternative uses,
which include:
           1.   Emission Control Regulation Development
           2.   Analysis of the Distribution of Benefits
           3.   Practical Model Application in AQCRs
           A.   Criteria for Evaluating Strategies
           5.   Other Uses of the C/B Model
8.1  EMISSION CONTROL REGULATION DEVELOPMENT
      Theoretical discussions of air pollution cost/benefit applications
generally concentrate on measurements of economic efficiency, that is, the
determination of the strategy under which the total cost of air pollution
disposal is minimized.  There has been no discussion in this report of
procedures which may be used to evaluate the geographical distribution of
air pollution costs and benefits within an AQCR.
      If cost/benefit analysis can be used to evaluate the impact of the
effects of an emission control strategy in AQCR,  it is reasonable to assume
that it can be applied in the development of emission control standards
(or regulations).  Emission standards have thus far been based on engineer-
ing analyses of sources and available control technology.  The allowable
emission rate is frequently expressed as a function of process or boiler
                                     99     PRECEDING

-------
size.   So chat no firms will be placed in an advantageous or disadvanta-
geous economic position relative to other competitive firms, emission
standards are generally applied uniformly to all sources in a region
(i.e., all firms bear the same burden).
      Such emission standards are generally promulgated and applied without
regard to the planning objectives of the AQCR, however.  Emission standards
currently tend to be economically ineffici'ent because they are uniformly
applied to all sources in the AQCR.  For critically located sources, such
emission standards are needed to satisfy air quality standards.  For sources
in other locations, such emission standards may be too stringent, as will
be seen in the following example.
      Particulate concentration distributions in the NCIAQCR before and
after application of emission standards are shown in Figure 8-1 and 8-2.
A cross-sectional view of pollution concentration relative to geographical
location is presented in Figure 8-3.  The upper and lower curves in Figure
8-3 represent pollutant concentrations before and after enactment of an
emission control strategy respectively.  The criterion for determining the.  .
acceptability of an emission control, strategy is that air quality at any
point in the region must meet or surpass the proposed air quality standard.
      Due to the uniform application of emission standards, the same level
of control is required for sources affecting the pollution concentration
in areas outside the center city as is required for sources affecting the
center city.  Since the long-term standard is based on the removal of all
identifiable effects which-lower the welfare of society, it may be asked
whether there is a need for further reduction in pollutant concentrations
at the perimeter of the region (that is, whether "non-degradation" Is
essential when existing pollutant concentrations are far below levels at
which effects are observed or welfare decreased).  The sources are being
treated equitably, but the receptors are not.  An economically inefficient
solution thus exists.
      This situation can be illustrated as in Figure 8-4, where source
equity (i.e., uniform application of emission standards for all sources
in an AQCR) is plotted as a function of receptor equity (i.e., equal
pollution concentration exposure for all receptors).  The curve shows
situations in which the condition of source equity is matched by receptor

                                    100

-------
                                     >>•  Vs'      -^.
~  Note:  Annual Concentrations in yg/ro
       Figure 8-1.  Existing Ground Level Particulate Concentrations in
                   the NCIAQCR as Computed by the Verified Diffusion Model
                                   101

-------
 Note:  Annual Concentrations in
Figure 8-2 .
Predicted Particulate Concentrations after Enactment
of the Proposed Emission Control Strategy'in all
Political Jurisdictions (Strategy 18)
                              102

-------
                                            EXISTING PARTICULATE
                                            CONCENTRATION
                                                                HEALTH CRITERIA FOR PARTICIPATES**
                                                                INTERIM STANDARD FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA**
                                                         j t _ ^CRITERIA FOR MATERIAL EFFECTS*
                                                                    TERM AIR QUALITY STANDARD FOR THE
                                                                DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA ****
                                                             - PARTICIPATE BACKGROUND LEVEL
                                                           PREDICTED PARTICULATE
20-
10-
n-
CENTER 	 J
CITY *|
CONCE
ENACT1
^ 	 REGUL
270
340
350
360
           ?80   .290    300.   310  ..  320.. .330
          UNITS OF THE UNIVERSAL TRANSVERSE MERCATQR. SCALE*
   *Measurements taken along  the"plane 5305 or tne Universal Transverse
    Mercator Scale,
  **Annual Geometric Mean  = 80 yg/m3.
 ***Annua^- Arithmetic Annual  Mean =,86.8 ug/m3.
a***^"1^1 9eometric Mean  = 60 ug/m3.  Annual Arithmetic Mean = 65.2  yg/m3.
****Standards proposed under  procedures  established  by  the Air Quality Act

                                                                          "
     Figure 8-3.    Predicted Air  Quality Improvement in the  NCIAQCR

-------
  SOURCE
  EQUITY
                            RECEPTOR EQUITY
           Figure 8-4.   Source Equity vs. Receptor Equity.
POLLUTANT
CONCENTRATION
AIR QUALITY
STANDARD

AIR QUALITY DIS-
TRIBUTION BEFORE

AIR QUALITY DIS-
TRIBUTION AFTER
                   GEOGRAPHICAL  DIVISIONS OF AN AQCR
                  Figure 8-5.   Source Equity (Position A)
                                 104

-------
inequity and vice versa (souce inequity and receptor equity).  Position A
on the curve corresponds to a situation involving source equity and receptor
inequity.  Such a situation is further shown in Figure 8-5.  A hypothetical
situation for Position B is shown in figure 8-6.
     The current application of emission standards is represented by Posi-
tion A.  Position B is typical of an emission standard based on geographical
location in the AQCR.  Figure 8-7 illustrates such an emission standard,
with control being more stringent in Zone W than in Zone X and so on (an
example of such a regulation would be the prohibition of automobile traffic
in the center city).  An emission standard which varies with geographical
location within an AQCR is likely to be more economically efficient for
society since, relative to a uniform standard, there is a control cost
saving with a negligible reduction in benefits.  The practicality of emis-
sion standards such as the one illustrated in Figure 8-7 should be deter-
mined.  There is likewise the need to re-examine the basis for developing
emission standards.  If an urban growth objective is to enhance the quality
of the downtown area through commercial development and construction of
middle-income residences, and at the same time to relocate industry outside
the center city, then emission standards based on a policy oriented toward
Position B would be compatible with regional goals.
     The above presentation has been designed to indicate ways in which
cost/benefit analysis can be used to examine new policy alternatives.  The
model is likewise useful as a means of evaluating existing policies.  The
important contribution made by the development of the C/B Model is the
ability to look at benefits (and damages) relative to specific geographical
areas in an AQCR.
8.2  ANALYSIS OF THE DISTRIBUTION
     The Cost/Benefit Model is capable of evaluating the distribution of
effects on the sources and receptors.  Equity evaluation of air pollution
control costs to firms affected is important in a competitive economy.   The
distribution of benefits resulting from cleaner air must likewino bft evalua-
ted for purposes of urban planning, land use, etc.   Some equity evaluations
which are possible with the Cost/Benefit Model are:
           1.   Compare the absolute pollutant concentration to
                income.  Although benefits (measured in dollars)
                                     105

-------
         t.
POLLUTANT
CONCENTRATION
AIR QUALITY
—- STANDARD
AIR QUALITY
DISTRIBUTION
AFTER
                                                       AIR QUALITY DIS-
                                                       TRIBUTION BEFORE
                   GEOGRAPHICAL  DIVISIONS OF AN AQCR
                Figure  8-6.   Source Equity  (Position B)
                                  106

-------
                                      ZONE Z
                                                         AQCR
                EMISSION STANDARD IN ZONE W MORE
                STRINGENT THAN IN ZONE X; ZONE X
                STANDARD MORE STRINGENT THAN ZONE Y;
                AND SO FORTH
Figure  8-7.   An Emission Standard Based on Geographical  Location
                               307

-------
     are not being considered here,  the relation-
     ship between actual air quality and income
     class will be valuable to a regional
     decision-maker who evaluates long-terra air
     quality trends and is cognizant of air pollu-
     tion interim.  Essentially the relationship
     in question is:
           I = f(AQ)       where: I = Income

     This relationship can be measured for existing
     conditions as well as under alternative regional
     control strategies.
2.    Compare the change in air quality resulting from
     a regional control strategy to income class.
     This comparison answers the question:  What
     improvement in air quality was obtained for
     each income class?  The relationship is as
     follows:

           AQ = g(I)

    The  change  in air  quality  can be measured  in two ways:

    a.   Absolute  improvement in  air quality  (e.g., wg/m3) where:

            (AQ)A  =  (AQ)b  -  (AQ)a


            (AQ)   = absolute  change in  air quality

            (AQ),  = air quality before  strategy

            (AQ)   = air quality after strategy.
                £L
    b.   Relative  improvement in  air quality  (e.g., %) where:

                  (AQ)   -  (AQ)

            (AQ)R      (AQ)b

            (AQ)   = relative  change in  air quality.
                R

3.  Comparison  of benefits  (in dollars)  resulting from a  re-
    gional  control strategy  to each income class,  i.e.,

          B  =  f(I)

4.  Comparison  of benefits  per income  (i.e., B/I)  resulting
    from a  regional  control  strategy for each  income class,
    i.e.,

           (B/I) = 8(1)
                          108

-------
                This  procedure  will  measure  the  improvement  in aggregate
                consumption  and productivity benefits  resulting from a
                given strategy  for each  income class.   This  is the most
                significant  measure  for  e.quity analyses,  since it  relates
                the importance  of benefits to individual  consumption
                levels (i.e., an additional  dollars worth of well-being
                for an individual earning $10 per  year is far more signifi-
                cant  than an additional  dollars  worth  of  well-being for an
                individual earning $10,000).  These data  may be presented
                as  follows:

                                                       (Benefit)
                      Income ($)_        Benefit  ($)     \Incoroe /(%)

                         2,000                80               4

                         4,000               120               3
                        25,000+             500              2

           5.  Analysis of benefits and benefit/income ratios  for non-
               white (NWT) and white (WT) sectors of a regional population.
               The procedure used could be as  follows:

               •  Divide census tracts into WT and NWT, where  a NWT tract
                  is defined as one having 50% or more non-white residents.

               •  Develop comparative data on  these tracts, as follows:
                                                             •
                  I($)   WT(B) ($)  NWT(B) ($)  WT(B/I) (%)  NWT(B/I) (%)
2,000
4,000
90
110
70
130
4.5
5.5
3.5
6.5
                 25,000     600         400         400          1.6

           6.  Analyses for an entire region as well as by individual
               political jurisdiction.

8.3  PRACTICAL MODEL APPLICATION IN AQCRs

     The Cost/Benefit Model will be initially applied as a research tool.

It is possible that the products of future research on damage functions and

in other -related areas may strengthen the capabilities of the Model to rhc>

extent that it will greatly enhance the sophistication of decision-making

                                    109'

-------
by regional control officers.  Development of the Model capabilities should
be in line with potential practical applications in the field.
     Once the Model becomes operational, it is necessary to determine how
it may be used most advantageously as part of a specific decision-making
process.  Figure 8-8 identifies possible points of Model application rela-
tive to various stages in air resource planning.  Initially, the Model
                                           *
could be.used for developing desirable air resource strategies consistent
with existing and projected economic activity and technology.  As air re-
source plans are implemented, it could be used to monitor the effectiveness
of the program and identify needed policy alterations.  After attainment of
a desirable air resource, the Model could be used in evaluating the steady-*-
state conditions and in establishing policies for future industrial growth,
land-use plans, etc.  Issues such as power plant siting and. solid waste
disposal techniques could be examined with the aid of the Model and appro-
         •
priate policies developed.
     The quality of the Model outputs will improve as the quality of the
input data improves.  Administrative programs such as source permit systems"
and air quality monitoring networks should provide more accurate input data
than are now available.  The future role of modeling should be examined in
light of the significant increase in data resources that will be available.
Any air resource program should have as an objective the optimum utilization
of all data collected.  An analytical model such as proposed represents one
method of extracting maximum value from data developed in the.field.  Addi-
tional research on the capabilities and practical uses of such a model would
be of considerable value.
8.4  CRITERIA FOR EVALUATING STRATEGIES
     In Chapter 3.0, the use of impact indicators (or, evaluation criteria)
in the decision-making process was discussed.  Currently, regional control
officers use a few quantitatively determined criteria in control strategy
decision-making (such as estimates of the probability of success in com-
plying with air quality standards and rough estimates of control costs) but
rely greatly on qualitative factors.  The field of air resource management
will improve as more reliable criteria are developed and used.-in the
decision-making process.  This section briefly identifies some criteria
and discusses the need for additional criteria development.
                                    110

-------
AVERAGE
REGIONAL
POLLUTION
CONCENTRATION
PLANNING
STABILIZATION
                                                     TIME
                                                                  ARE ; =   AIR RESOURCE EVALUATION
                         Figure 8-8.  Use of the Cost/Benefit Model in an AOCR

-------
     The Cost/Benefit Model produces indicators wiiich, by themselves, arc
useful in evaluating control strategies.  Such indicators may be developed
from the model's control cost and benefit estimates and can be referred to
as "control impact indicators" and "effects impact indicators."  When an
economic model system is used to determine the effects of control costs
and benefits on regional economic activity, indicators on unemployment,
regional output, investment and consumption are produced.  These are the
traditional economic indicators.  Finally, there has been developing in
this country an interest in creating and utilizing "social indicators" in
the evaluation of public programs.  The state-of-the-art in devising social
indicators to measure the well-being of society is still very rudimentary.
                                                                       *•
This section briefly discusses the different types of indicators.
     Control impact indicators are useful tools for evaluating efficiency
and equity aspects of air resource policies as they affect sources in an
AQCR.  Woodcock and Barrett have discussed the development of impact indi-
cators and their application in the gray iron foundry industry.   Such
indicators make it possible to compare  impacts for various emitters and
can be used  in judging  the efficiency of an air resource management program
and determining whether emission control regulations distribute air pollu-
tion control expenditures equitably among the firms affected.
     Effects impact indicators are developed by converting social benefits
to  incremental changes  in labor and capital productivity.  Examples of such
indicators are:
           •   The change in productivity of an industrial
               activity resulting from  the social benefit
               derived  from reduced plant maintenance, reduced
               absenteeism of labor, more productive  labor
                (because of improved health and mental attitude),
               less corrosion.of facilities exposed to the
               atmosphere, increased value of plant property
                (which could be rented or put to other economic
               uses), etc., and,
   Woodcock,  K.  R.,  and Barrett,  L.  B.,  "Economic  Indicators  of  the  Impact
   of Air Pollution  Control;  Gray Iron  Foundries:   A Case  Study," Journal
   of the Air Pollution Control Association, Vol.  20, No.  2,  pp. 72-77,
   February 1970.
                                    112

-------
           •   The change in productivity of an agricultural
               activity because of reduced plant damage,
               livestock illness, etc.

     Such indicators are useful in evaluations of relative benefits received

by sectors of a region from air resource policies (e.g. , rich vs. poor,

whites vs. non-whites, inner city vs. suburbia).

     Economic modeling is required to develop economic indicators for the

air resource decision-making process.  Economic indicators reflect the

impacts from control costs, the demand for air pollution control equipment,

the resulting increase in regional welfare (from benefits), etc.  Such

effects create a shift in the economic structure of the region.  Air pollu-

tion control policies lead to changes in economic output, labor markets,

availability of capital, and distribution of capital within the economy.

     The economics model system developed by CONSAD is capable of estimating

such impacts in the economy.  The model system was designed to provide the

following types of information for use in public-policy analyses:

           1.  Regional economic changes expected to result
               from application of various emission standards
               to major polluters.

           2,  Regional economic effects expected to result
               from reduction of industrial damage and growth
               in air pollution equipment industries.

           3.  Changes in regional output, investment, employ-
               ment, income, and consumption associated with
               various emission standards.

           4.  Fiscal effects of regional implementation of
               air quality control programs. Such effects
               include the tax base impacts of economic change
               and the rate of achievement of emission standards
               specified in the implementation plan.

           5.  Statistical indicators, including industry-specific
               ratios of air pollution control costs to total in-
               vestment and to value added in production.1
1
  A Cross-Sectional Regional Economics Model for RAPA-II Air Pollution
  Control Analysis, CONSAD Research Corporation, Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania,
  pp. 3, June 1970.

                                   113

-------
     The system produces some of the following economic indicators:
           •   Gross regional product
           •   Employment change by industry
           •   Investment change and capital stock by industry
           •   Industry value added.
     Raymond A. Bauer1 has defined social indicators as "yardsticks by
which to know if the social condition" is getting better or worse."  Such
indicators are recommended for the air resource decision-making process.
They should not merely reflect measures of air quality, but must represent
social welfare resulting from the costs and benefits of pollution control
policies.  The President's Task Force on Economic Growth has stated that,
in order to improve the environment and facilitate economic growth and
progress, "the appropriate Federal  agency should develop indicators of
social and economic well-being to guide long-term public policy."2  The
report of the National Goals Research Staff states:
           "While we have come to appreciate the complexity of
           social and environmental processes, our present know-
           ledge of those complex processes is extraordinarily
           incomplete.  From this, it follows that for the long
           range we must vigorously pursue the extension of our
           knowledge in these processes.  And, for the short.
           range, since our ability to anticipate exactly what
           will happen is so limited, we must sharpen our ability
           to detect as rapidly as possible that which has al-
           ready happened.  This requires the development of new
           improved methods for the measurement of social change."3
     A list of readings on social indicators is included in the
Bibliography.
1      . .. ..-T._-Tf.«*er .-.XC
  Bauer, R. A., Social Indicators, MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass. 1966.
2
  Policies for American Economic Progress in the Seventies, Report of the
  President's Task Force on Economic Growth, May 1970, p. 2.
3
  Toward Balanced Growth;  Quantity with Quality, Report of the National
  Goals Research Staff, Washington, D. C., 4 July 1970.
                                    114

-------
 8.5  OTHER USES OF THE
-------
           •  Control system evaluations  -  Evaluations  of  the  results
              of control  by
                    fuel  switching only
                    fuel  switching with  specific fuels  only
                    maximum feasible technology on certain sources
                    only, etc.
       The role of the analyst  will be to develop situations which  are
relevant to more efficient and  equitable  policies and,  by  testing the
situations, to gain"further knowledge for decision-making  purposes.
                                       v  KV

                                        IP' £'
                                        / *•  ,^-L ifi*
                                        I  <.  ^ >O
                                            >>.'-'
                                      •AV'*:-


                                             .-j
                                              •S
                                               i
                                    116
                                       "/   .?  '
                                             "j.'

-------
                           9.0  BIBLIOGRAPHY
9.1  REGIONAL.AIR QUALITY MANAGEMENT

      Atkisson, Arthur, and Richard S. Gaines, Development of Air Quality
      Standards. Columbus, Ohio:  Charles E. Merrill Publishing Co., 1969.

      Schueneman, Jean J., "Air Pollution Control Administration,"
      Chapter 52 in Arthur Stern, Air Pollution (Second Edition), New
      York:  Academic Press, 1968, pp. 719-796.

      Williams, James D., and Normal G. Edmisten, An Air Resource Manage-
      ment Plan for the Nashville Metropolitan Area, U, S. Department of
      Health, Education and Welfare, Public Health Service, Cincinnati,
      Ohio, 1965.

9.2  GENERAL COST/BENEFIT LITERATURE

      Alchian, Armen A., "The Rate of Interest, Fisher's Rate of Return
      over Costs and Keyes' Internal Rate of Return," The American
      Economic Review. Vol. 45, No. 5, 1955, pp. 938-943.

      Buchanan, James M., "Positive Economics, Welfare Economics, and
      Political Economy," Journal of Law and Economics, Vol.  3, October
      1960, pp. 124-138.

      Buchanan, James M., and William Craig Stubblebine, "Externality,"
      Economica, Vol. 29, November 1962, pp. 371-384.

      Chase, Samuel B. Jr., ed., Problems in Public Expenditure Analysis,
      Washington, D. C.:  The Brookings Institution, 1968.

      Coase, R.H., "The Problem of Social Cost," Journal of Law and
      Economics. Vol. 3, October 1960, pp. 1-44.

      Davis, Otto A., and Andrew Whinston, "Externalities, Welfare, and
      the. Theory of Games," Journal of Political Economy, Vol.  30, June
      1962, pp. 241-262.

      Dolbear, F.T., Jr., "On the Theory of Optimum Externality," American
      Economic Review, March 1967, pp.

      Dorfman, Robert, ed., Measuring Benefits of Government  Investments,
      Washington, D. C. :  The Brookings Institution, 1965.

      Dorfman, R. , P.A. Samuelson., and R.M. Solow, Linear Programming
      and Economic Analysis, New York:  McGraw Hill, 1968.

      Foley, Duncan K., "Resource Allocation and the Public Sector,"
      Yale Economic Essays, Vol. 7, Spring 1967, pp. 45-98.
                                   117

-------
      Hinrichs, Harley H.,  and Graeme M. Taylor, Program Budgeting and
      Benefit/Cost Analysis, Pacific Palisades, California:  Goodyear
      Publishing Co. Inc.,  1969.

      Krutilla, John V., "Welfare Aspects of Benefit/Cost Analysis,"
      Journal of Political  Economy, Vol. 69, No. 3, June 1961, pp. 226-
      235.

      Maass, Arthur, "Benefit/Cost Analysis:  Its Relevance to Public
      Investment Decisions," Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol.
      May 1966, pp. 208-226.

      Marglin, Stephen A.,  Public Investment Criteria, Cambridge:   MIT
      Press, 1967.

      McCullough, J.D., Cost Analysis for Pla'nnihg-Programming-Budgeting
      Cost Benefit Studies, Santa Monica, California:   The Rand Corpora-
      tion, November 1966.

      Margolis, Julius, "Secondary Benefits, External  Economies, and the
      Justification of Public Investment," Review of Economics and Sta-
      tistics. Vol. 39, No. 3, August 1957, pp. 284-291.

      Miller, William L., "The Magnitude of the Discount Rate for Govern-
      ment Projects," Southern Economic Journal, Vol.  28, No. 4, 1962,
      pp. 348-356.

      Prest, A.R., and R. Turvey, "Cost/Benefit Analysis:* A Survey,"
      The Economic Journal, Vol.  75, No. 300, pp. 683-735.

      Rothenberg, Jerome, Economic Evaluation of Urban Renewal, Washington,
      D. C.:  The Brookings Institution, 1967.

      Schaller, Howard G.,  ed., Public Expenditure Decision in the Urban
      Community, Washington, D. C.:  Resources for the Future, Inc., 1963.

      Turvey, Ralph, "On Divergences between Social Cost and Private Costs,"
      Economica, Vol. 30, August  1963, pp. 309-313.

      U.S. 91st Congress, 1st Session, The Analysis and Evaluation of
      Public Expenditures;   The PPB System, Joint Economic Committee,
      Congress of the United States, Volumes 1, 2, and 3, Washington,
      D. C.:  U.S. Government Printing Office, 1969.

9.3  THEORY AND APPLICATION OF COST/BENEFIT ANALYSIS IN WATER RESOURCES

      Bain, Joe S., "Criteria for Undertaking Water-Resource Developments,"
      American Economic Review, No. 50, May 1960, pp.  310-320.

      Brown, Gardner, and C.B. McGuire, "A Socially Optimum Pricing Policy
      for a Public Water Agency," Water Resources Research, First  Quarter,
      1967, No. 3, pp. 33-43.
                                   118

-------
      Ciriacy-Wantrup,  S.V.,  "Water Policy  and Economic Optimizing:
      Some Conceptual Problems in Water Research,"  American Economic
      Review,  Vol.  57,  No.  2, 1967, pp. 179-196.

      Freeman, A.  Myrick,  III, "Adjusted Benefit/Cost  Ratios for Six
      Recent Reclamation Projects," Journal of Farm Economics,  Vol.  48,
      No.  4. 1966,  pp.  1002-1012.

      Freeman, A.  Myrick,  III, "Income  Distribution and Planning for
      Public Investment,"  American Economic Review, Vol.  57, No.  3,  1967,
      pp.  495-508.

      Hirshleifer,  Jack, and  J.W. Milliman, "Urban  Water Supply:   A
      Second Look," American  Economic Review,  Vol.  57,  No.  2, 1967,
      pp.  169-178.

      Kneese,  Allen V., and Blair T.  Bower, Managing Water  Quality:
      Economics,  Technology,  Institutions,  Baltimore;   Johns Hopkins
      Press, 1968.

      Schmid,  A.  Allan, "Economic Analysis  of  Water Resource Problems-
      Nonmarket Values and Efficiency of Public Investments in  Water
      Resources," American Economic Review, Vol,  57, No.  2, 1967,  pp.
      158-168.

9.4  RELEVANT AIR POLLUTION AND RELATED LITERATURE

      Anderson, Robert J.,  Jr., and Thomas  D.  Crocker,  "Air Pollution and
      Housing:  Some Findings," Paper No. 264,  Institute for.Research in
      the  Behavioral, Economic, and Management Sciences,  Purdue University,
      Lafayette,  Indiana,  January 1970.

      Barrett, Larry B., and  Thomas E.  Waddell,  "The Cost of  Air Pollution
      Damages: A Status Report," U.S.D.H.E.W.,  National Air Pollution Con-
      trol Administration,  Raleigh, North Carolina, June  1970 (unpublished).
                                                \
                                                \
      Burton,  E.S., and William Sanjour, "A Simulation  Approach to Air
      Pollution Abatement  Program Planning," Socio-Economic Planning
      Science, Vol. 4,  Pergaraon Press,  1970, pp.  147-150.

      Cost Effectiveness of Air Pollution Control Strategies (Course Man-
      ual, Institute for Air  Pollution  Training), U.S.  Department  of
      Health,  Education, and  Welfare, Public Health Service, Consumer
      Protection  and Environmental Health Service.

      Duke University School  of Law,  L^aw and Contemporary Problems,
      Vol. 33, Spring 1968, pp. 195-426.

      Economic Benefits from  Public Health^Services -  Objectives,  Methods,
      and_Kxamples  of Measurement, U.S. Department  of,-Health, Education,
      and  Welfare,  Public  Health Service, Washington,  D.  C., 1967.
                                   119

-------
Krnst and Ernst, A Cost-Ef f ecciveness Study of Air Pollution  Ab_ate-
inent in the Greater Kansas City Area, Summary Statement  to  the  Kansas
City, Kansas-Kansas City, Missouri Air Pollution Abatement  Conference,
May .L968.

Ernst and Ernst, National Capital Area, A Cost-Effectiveness  Study
of Air Pollution Abatement, Submitted by Ernst and Ernst  as an
Exhibit for the Record  to the Washington, D. C. Air Pollution
Abatement Conference, 1969.

Frankel, M.L. , and D.H. Lewis, "Regional Air Pollution Analysis,"
Paper presented at the  Fourth Conference on Application  of  Simulation,
December 9-11, 1970, New York, pp. 82-93.

Klarman, Herbert E. , "Present Status-, o-jE Cost/Benefit  Analysis in
the Health Field," American Journaj. 'pjCtf^lic Health, No. 57, Novem-
ber 1967, pp. 1948-1953.

Klarman, Herbert E. , The Economics f.v^lth, New York:   Columbia
University Press, 196^!               ""
                                     '   /
Klarman, Herbert E. , ed. , Empirical gtudies in Health Economics,
Baltimore: . Johns Hopkins Press,
Lave, Lester B. , and Eugene P. Seskinf, '&Jr' pollution  and  Human
Health," Science, Vol. 169, No.  3547, LjOtst- 1970, pp.  723-733.
                          .        '    'iffif
Lind, Robert C. , "Land Market Equilifc''J«£i>  and  the Measurement  of
Benefits from Urban Programs," Paper ( ''^9tited  at the  CUE  Conference,
September 11-12, 1970.           . . .; ;
Michelson, I., and B. Tourin, "Comp-aa'at^v  ^Method  for  Studying Costs
of Air Pollution," Public Health Reptfrft ;.]Vol.  81, No.  6,  June 1966,
pp. 505-511.

Nourse, Hugh 0., "The Effect of Airf'l>l|: jfon on House  Values,"
Land Economics. Vol. 43, No. 2, MayJ  /6V.' &o. 181-189.
Rice, Dorothy P., Estimating  the Co£ _ f   ?.Jlhess ,  Health  Economics
Series, No. 6, U.S. Department of H& -,,,    .cUJucation  and  Welfare,
Public Health Service, Washington, EJL  '.'.  "^ 1966.
                                     "W '  . • »
Ridker, Ronald G. , Economic Costs of m? dilution,  Studj.es  in
Measurement, New York:  Frederick A. ^ ,«• t-p.  1967.
                                     . 6 *' *   • .-'
                                      W
Ridker, Ronald G. , and John A. Henniu-g, "The Determinants  of Resi-
dential Property Values with Special Steference to Air  Pollution,"
The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 49, May 1967, pp.  246-
257.                                      :
                              120

-------
      U.S. 92nd Congress, 1st Session, Senate, Economics of Clean Air,
      Third Report of the Administrator of the Environmental Protection
      Agency to the Congress of the United States in Compliance with
      Public Law 90-148, The Clean Air Act, as Amended, Washington, D. C.:
      U. S. Government Printing Office, January 1971.

      U. S. 91st Congress, 2nd Session, Senate, National Emission Standards
      Study, Report of the Secretary of Health, Education, and Welfare
      to the United States Congress in Compliance with Public Law 90-148,
      The Clean Air Act, as Amended, Washington, D.  C.:  U. S. Government
      Printing Office, March 1970.

      Weisbrod, Burton A., Economics of Public Health  - Measuring the
      Economic Impact of Diseases, Philadelphia:  University of Pennsyl-
      vania Press, 1961.

      Wilson, Richard D., and David W. Minnotte, "A Cost/Benefit Approach
      to Air Pollution Control," Journal o£ the Air Pollution Control
      Association. Vol. 19, No. 5, May 1969, pp. 303-308.

      Wolozin, Harold, ed., The Economics of Air Pollution, New York:
      W.W. Norton and Company, Inc., 1966.

      Woodcock, Kenneth R. , and Larry B,, Barrett, "Economic Indicators
      of the Impact of Air Pollution Control, Gray Iron Foundries:  A
      Case Study," Journal of the Air Pollution Control Association,
      Vol. 20, No. 2, February 1970, pp. 72-77.

9.5  SOCIAL INDICATORS

      Bauer, Raymond A. ed., Social Indicators, Cambridge:  MIT Press,
      1966.

      Bell, Daniel, "The Idea of a Social Report," The Public Interes^,
      No. 16, Spring 1969.

      Policies for American Economic Progress in the Seventies, The
      Report of the President's Task Force on Economic Growth, May 1970.

      Sheldon, Eleanor B. and Wilbert Moore, eds. , Indicators of Social
      Change, New York:  Russell Sage Foundation, 1968.

      Toward A Social Report, U.S. Department'of Health, Education, and
      Welfare, Washington, D. C., 1969.

      Toward Balanced Growth;  Quantity with Quality,  Report of the
      National Coals Research Staff, Washington, D.  C., July 1970.
                                   121

-------
                                APPENDIX A

      THEORETICAL CONSIDERATIONS OF AIR POLLUTION COST/BENEFIT ANALYSIS

      This section briefly reviews some theoretical considerations of air
pollution cost/benefit analysis.  Various sources in the"welfare economics
literature have been reviewed to better understand the manner in which
cost/benefit analysis is applied in other public programs.  The discussion
here attempts to relate the principles of cost/benefit analysis to air
pollution.
      The social costs of air pollution control affect the individual, the
corporate sector, and the public sector.  Individual costs represent an
incremental portion of the consumption benefits.  Such costs might take the
form of annual incremental costs of products that are altered for air qua-
lity purposes (i.e., fuels for home heating, gasoline for  automobiles, etc.)
or annual incremental costs of activities which' replace activities that are
outlawed by air pollution control regulations (e.g., the cost of solid
waste removal"and disposal when backyard burning is prohibited).
      The corporate sector feels the impact of air pollution control costs
through emission reduction activities, air quality monitoring and research
and development on process innovations or pollution controls.  The impact
of these costs may be passed on to the individual in the form of an increase
in the price of the goods and services marketed.  Without  emission control,
the cost of air pollution is transferred to the community  in the form of
damages in this case referred to as external diseconomies  or negative ex-
ternalities, since the costs are negative benefits and are external to the
firm.  The justification for air pollution control is based on the premise
that it is socially cheaper to control emissions at the source (i.e., to
increase the internalities) than it is to bear the cost of a polluted air
resource (i.e., to live with the externalities).
      Public expenditures for pollution control are associated with  (1) en-
forcement of individual and corporate control activities,  (2) reduction of
emissions from public facilities,  (3) regional and nation-wide monitoring
of pollution concentrations,  (4) research and development on new control
techniques and instruments, and (5) research on air pollution effects.
                                           PRECEDING PAffi BLANK

-------
 Wlien evaluating the cost of air pollution control  to  the public  sector,
 allocation of annual revenues at the federal, state,  and local levels  of
 government must be measured.  The impact of these  costs is  felt  by  the
 individual in the form of increased taxes.
      Social benefits, like  social costs, have an impact on  the individual,
 the corporate sector, and the public sector.  The  social benefits  to be
 measured in cost/benefit analysis are  the technological or  "real"  effects
 which alter the total production possibilities and total welfare opportuni-
 ties for consumers in the economy.  The economic effects of air pollution
 have been grouped as follows: •
            •   Direct effects - the di-reg^-^nd immediate
                externalities borne by 'jfty /"V.ceptor
                                       '/'H   '
            9   Adjustments  (Indirect e£ l^ffi) - effects which
                induce persons and firm*/'to make certain ad-
                justments in order to reduce ^the direct impact
                of the pollutants.      {.
            •   Market effects - effects/jtealiwd through the
                marketplace as a result, os Jfya*'adjustments made.
      One classification of the direct eftefcts of air pollution is shown in
                                        *   • 'v>-
 Figure A-l.*  The concept of the social •«;/ .V'^of adjustment is illustrated
                                      • "-  ''•' ;-  •
 in Figure A-2.  Adjustments result fro^tf•;._'jirect effects of air pollution
 on property and the individual.  Socie\$ &• yilling to pay a price to avoid
 the inconvenience or dissatisfaction r<&uV Jg from these effects.  Figure
                                        'x  1  .i
 A-3 illustrates the manner in which ttwS in  Sidual feels the effects of air
                                       ""A    I
 pollution.  A structure of the type s^i-8n •< 7 Figure A-3 is required as a
                                       I, ;||  ! '  t 1
 starting point for classification of t?*3lt£  »i> costs and benefits of emis-
                                       i wBli  .1 -i
 sion control strategies.
      In discussing the effects of publV"?'xc.grams, a major economic dis-
                                        v:>
 tinction is drawn between pecuniary effejrrsr «nd technological effects.
 Pecuniary effects are the result of ch«\e!»-.yi relative prices in the
 economy.  They involve a redistribution of goods and services among people,
 "Technological effects" (also called "real" effects) alter the total pro-
 duction possibilities or total welfare possibilities for consumers in the
*Barrett, L. B. and T. E. Waddell, "The Cost^of Air Pollution Damages:  A
 Statur Report," (unpublished paper).  >_    f£.:
                                    124 |
                                        ir*
                                        r-  n

-------
                                      HUMAN
                                      HEALTH  EFFECTS
EFFECTS
ON ANIMALS
  DETERIORATION
  OF
  MATERIALS
                                  PSYCHOLOGICAL
                                  AND ESTHETIC
                                  EFFECTS
                      VEGETATION
                      EFFECTS
Figure A-l.   Classification of Direct Effects
                           125

-------
                      EFFECTS
                     -ON
                      ANIMALS
VEGETATION
EFFECTS
                    MATERIALS
                    DETERIORATION
. THE "WILLINGNESS TO PAY"
 TO AVOID THE EFFECTS
 RESULTING FROM
        Figure  A-2.   Identification of  Adjustments
                                126

-------
10
-J
                IWNERSHIP

            KFKKCTS
              DIRECT
             ADJUSTMENTS
              MARKET
                                               ECONOMIC EFFECTS  OF AIR,POLLUTION
                                        COST OF POLLUTION
INDIVIDUAL
CORPORATE
PUBLIC
                                             MARKET
                                             PRICES
                             INDIVIDUAL
                             OR
                             HOUSEHOLD
                             WELFARE
                                                      COST OF POLLUTION CONTROL
INDIVIDUAL
                                TAXES
                                                           CORPORATE
                                               MARKET
                                               PRICES
                                             INDIVIDUAL
                                             OR
                                             HOUSEHOLD
                                             WELFARE
                                                               PUBLIC
                                                                              TAXES
                     Figure A-3.    Structuring the Economic Effects of Air  Pollution

-------
 economy.  These  effects  are  termed "economies" when  they  are  favorable  and
 "diseconomies" when  they  are  unfavorable.  Thus, manpower training  programs
 produce  real benefits  for  trainees  insofar as they increase the workers'
 productive capabilities.   Once  the  trainee is part of  the  training  program,
 the  benefits are classified  as  internal  real benefits  or  economies  ("inter-
 nal" because the effects  are  borne  by  the firm that  does  the  training).

 Classic  examples of  external  real  economies a*re  air  and water pollution.
 These  effects  are classified  as "external" because they are borne by  per-
 sons other  than  those  who caused  the pollution.  They  are considered  "real"
 because  production or  consumption  opportunities  elsewhere in  the economy
                                            t
 are  reduced, since polluted  water  is a detriment to  other uses of water
 (i.e., commercial, drinking,  swimming, etc/"
                                         /$»•
     The concepts of pecuniary  and real  greets  would  be  applicable,  for
 example,  to  a  shift  in output from firms which'liquidate  because of exces-
 sive costs of  air pollution  control (as  well as  other  firms)  to firms which
 supply control equipment.  The  resulting ire*rea&e'.in revenues to the  sup-
 pliers of control equipment  is  a pecuniary e^wfeft  {i.e.,  a redistribution).
 The  important  consideration  is  that only a 3^ft within the economy exists,
                                              >
 without  an  increase  or decrease in  the prodr.. tfuity  of the economy  as a
 whole.*   Technological  effects  are  felt  b£v.$Vj£.}3 which must purchase hard-
                                             vf 7?" '?
 ware,  switch fuels,  install monitoring- deyicef '' or  perform research.  When
 the  responsibility  for  pollution  control i§ pi . :' >d  upon  the pollutant
 emitter,  costs  are  internalized and measured o.  the balance sheet of the
                                           '^  \ I
 firm,  instead of  being  passed along as an,'/>te' slity to  the community.
 Such costs  are  felt  as  a  net decrease  in p  'ddf  ^lyity for the  total economy,
                                           ? A*   v/
 since  the same  quantity of product  is  beini.v^'  Aiced at an increased cost.
                                           .
 This  decrease  in net  productivity  is  a  relt V ji' Asocial cost for cost/benefit
                                           v^i* •
 analysis.
      As  was  the  case  with  social costs,  eff£ '7s •'&*-&  identified as either
                                            '. j
 pecuniary  or technological in the  evaluation of  social benefits.  For  ex-
 ample, air pollution  control  may reduce demand for certain products  and
*This discussion assumes a market economy without .serious imperfections.

                                    128

-------
services in some sectors of the economy  (e.g., window-washing, house-
painting), thus causing a shift in output from these sectors to the rest
of  the economy.  The  reduction in revenues for the sector in which demand
is  reduced and the  corresponding increase in demand and in revenues for
the rest of the economy are pecuniary effects.  The net increase in aggre-
gate consumption or aggregate production benefits which the society realizes
from improved air quality represents a technological effect and a social
benefit.   For  example, as an  individual  becomes more productive  (because
of  improved health  or enhanced psychological attitude) or as he derives
more satisfaction  from a given income  (i.e., through increased welfare or
income utility), social benefits for society increase accordingly.

      Another concept employed in cost/benefit  analysis is that of the so-
called  "secondary effect" of a project.—   As the term is generally used,
such effects represent the external pecuniary effects of the project.
They include the results of  changes in demand for particular resource input;
used by the project and the  accompanying changes in income of the resource
owners.   The results of changes in the demand pattern for particular output:
as well as the accompanying  changes in incomes  of  their sellers,  as the
initial beneficiaries spend  their added income  and the initial cost-bearers
reduce  their spending, are likewise considered  to  be secondary effects.
Such "re-spending"  is essentially a byproduct or side-effect of a project
and does  not reflect any increase in the economy's total productive capa-
bility,  since such  increases are already counted in the real benefits.
Secondary effects, reflect shifts in relative demand patterns which produce
increased income for some persons and decreased incomes for  others.
      Secondary benefits thus represent the values added by  incurring
secondary costs in activities stemming from or  induced  by the project
(i.e.,  indirect contributions of  public investment to aggregate consump-
tion).  The principle sources of  secondary benefits are:
 4  The discussion here on secondary  effects  and  intangible  effects  is  based
   on B.  A.  Weisbrod's,  "Concepts  of Costs and Benefits," in  S.  B.  Chase,
   Jr.,  ed.,  Problems in Public Expenditure  Analysis,  Brookings  Institution,
   Washington,  D.  C., pp.  257-262, 1968.
                                    129

-------
           o  Departures from competition in the further processing of
              goods and services produced by means of public project
              outputs.
           •  Changes in consumption sufficient to produce changes in  the
              price of consumer goods.
           •  External economies associated with public projects.
           •  Private investment induced by public projects.

     It is common in cost/benefit analyses to distinguish between costs
and benefits that are "tangible" and those that are "intangible." Tangible
effects can be measured and priced for decision-making purposes, intangi-
ble effects cannot.  In other words, tangible effects include those for
which, at a particular point in time, data are available whereby the
effects may be assessed a value placed on them (in the form of shadow
prices).  In this connection, Weisbrod comments as follows:  "In short,
what is tangible or intangible, measurable or non-measurable, is less a
matter of what is abstractly possible than it is of what is pragmatically,
and at reasonable costs, feasible."1  He emphasizes the point that what is
intangible today because of data limitations may be tangible tomorrow as a
                                                        »
result of research efforts aimed at quantification of effects, citing the
following analogy:  "In the Middle Ages and earlier it must surely have
been argued by some that one's feeling of warmth or cold was intangible,
unmeasurable, and so on.  Fortunately, Gabriel Fahrenheit did not agree."2
     The concept of intangible and tangible effects is of great importance
in air pollution control.  Since most of the effects of a polluted atmos-
phere are now considered intangible, qualitative considerations will In-
fluence decisions concerning the development of a regional air resource
plan.  For decision-making purposes, such intangible effects must be iden-
tified and ranked according to their importance.  As planned research
efforts are implemented, more data will become available-and additional
air pollution effects may be quantified.
1
  Ibid.  pg.  261
2
  Ibid.  pg.  261
                                    130

-------
      The distinction  between tangible  and  intangible  effects has  been
 made.   It should  be noted  that  intangible  effects  can and do affect  the
 decision-making process.   As research  progresses,  there  should be a
 trend  toward  more complete identification  and  evaluation of effects,
 with a corresponding  decline in the  influence  of intangible effects
 upon policy decisions.

     Having identified the relevant costs and benefits and some of the
 essential  terminology of cost/benefit analysis, additional aspects of
 economic efficiency are now  reviewed.  This material  should serve as a
 guide  for  some  of  the analyses  that are possible with  the Cost/Benefit
 Model.
     The use of cost/benefit analysis to determine the economic efficiency
 of alternative  control strategies is illustrated in Figure A-A.  The upper
 graph  shows one way of plotting pollution and control  cost curves for a
 hypothetical AQCR.  These  theoretical curves are based on the control costs
 and  pollution damage costs for  five increasingly stringent emission control
 strategies  (S   through S ).  As the stringency of the  control strategies
 increases,  there  is a corresponding reduction in the  regional pollution
 concentration.
      Costs of pollution damage and control are determined  for each
 strategy^ (e.g., CC, ,  and CP, *  for strategy S ).   Above the two. cost
 curves is a "total cost to society" curve which is a summation of control
and damage costs.   The marginal cost of control increases as control
efficiency increases,  and the marginal cost of pollution increases as
pollution concentration increases, as shown in the lower, graph.  The
minimum cost to society thus corresponds to the intersection of the control
 cost and cost of pollution curves.
      Control costs,  and benefits are illustrated in Figure A-5.   The
control cost curve in this illustration is identical to that in Figure A-4.
The benefits curve represents the differences, in pollution costs under
 existing conditions (S ) and under various emission control strategies.
The benefit, B, for strategy S  for example is the difference between
 pollution costs under  strategies SQ and S .  The optimum welfare condi-
 tion for society is represented by strategy S., where  the absolute differ-
 ence between benefits and costs reaches its maximum value.   From  the lower
                                   131

-------
    COST  OF
    CONTROL
N
O
u
                                                         TOTAL COST
                                                         TO SOCIETY
COST OF
 'OLLUTION
DAMAGE
            POLLUTION CONCENTRATION (yg/ra )
         MARGINAL COST
         OF CONTROL
z
o
M
jj
s
CJ
z
§
M
H
O
Ou.
O
u
                               MARGINAL COST
                               OF POLLUTION
                               DAMAGE
            POLLUTION  CONCENTRATION (yg/o )

       Figure A-4.  Cost  of  Control and  Cost  of  Pollution
                                 132

-------
CO
H
CO
8

1
H
SB
8
CO
H
CO
8
Ul
u
CO
                                             BENEFITS
   AVERAGE REGIONAL^FaiLOTION CONCENTRATION (wg/m )
 e
 60


H
CO
8
§
H
3
55
12
O
MARGINAL
COST OF
CON
.   MARGINAL
'.  BENEFITS
                                                           ''*<£
   AVERAGE REGIONAL POLLUTION CONCENTRATION (ug/m )
            Figure A-5.   Cost of Control and Benefits
                               i ">'
                               .L-j.

-------
graph it is evident that for strategy S., marginal benefits equal marginal
costs.   This condition of maximum welfare, referred to in economics as
the Pareto optimum, exists when one more dollar spent on'improving the
welfare of one individual necessarily detracts from the welfare of another.
Thus under strategy S  if one dollar more is spent on the control of
emissions,  benefits valued  at less  than  a dollar will be gained.  On  the
other hand, if one dollar less  is spent  on control, more than  a dollar's
worth of benefits will be lost.
      This  concept is further illustrated in Figure  A-6, where the
abscissa represents "tons of emissions -removed"  (under various emission
                                       if. *>>.
control strategies) rather  than  "regional /^flution concentration"  (this
change reverses  the location of  the margi/&A&ost and marginal benefit
curves - see Appendix B  for 'a discussionf&f a iterative  "measures of
                                               *
pollution"  for plotting  costs and benefits.  AS in Figure A-5, the Pareto
optimility  condition exists where welfare is maximized.
                                          f & i •'V'••
      As Figure A-6 indicates, the  goal  of th*x«p.r ^resource decision-maker
                                         >"    t 'i ^-
is to remove the Pareto-relevant damages.  Nb^jlans will be included  for
                                             .<••> •
elimination of Pareto-irrelevant damages, -si^ce for these, the benefits
                                         ' .  " '>
derived from pollution control will be less*r>:V<5 the costs of  controlling
                                          -V'iSjM
the pollutants.  For maximum efficiency, ££-, £UT -^nportant that  a pollution
                                          •"?  Bw» • . •-,.
control policy provide for removal of Parefco-t  -evant damages only.
Benefits under the Pareto-optimura strategy are represented by quadrangle
AECB and the cost of pollution control, by \rii.gle BEC.  The net benefit
                                            )  f $
to society is thus represented by triangle 4EB/"LAs shown in Figure  A-7,
it is desirable to internalize the Pareto-) »*# ljt externalities (i.e.,
                                           f V>>,' %                      '   •
by making the polluting sources pay the coft'Ai^ ^ost) without infringing
upon the Pareto-irrelevant externalities. \£Jrjt'her words, it is desirable
to control pollution at the source up to a pq%?t where the next dollar
                                            fff
 spent  on  pollution control  is  equal  to  the -Insulting  incremental social
 benefits  obtained by  the  community.
     The  shaded area  under  the marginal control  cost  and  marginal  benefit
 functions in Figure A-8 represents total air pollutant  disposal cost to
 society at  the  maximum welfare condition.   This  total cost may  be  reduced
                                     13A     u <*
                                             £U---
                                             )lf

-------
    w
    03
    H
    to
    8
                       PARETO-OPTIMALITY
                            MC - MB
                                                     MARGINAL
                                                     .BENEFITS
                                  IRRELEVAN
                                iSDAMAGES
                                                     MARGINAL
                                                     CONTROL
                                                     COSTS
                     REGIONAL TONS REMOVED
Figure A-6.  Pareto-Relevant and Pareto-Irrelevant Externalities
                                 135

-------
                PARETO  -  IRRELEVANT
                   EXTERNALITIES
                 PARETO -  RELEVANT
                   EXTERNALITIES
                   INTERNALIZES
Figure  A-7.   Internalization of the Cost of Pollution
                          136

-------
to

H
I-C

U.

W
CQ


Q
H
CO

8
§
M
O
                                                            MARGINAL

                                                            CONTROL

                                                            COST
                                                            MARGINAL

                                                            BENEFITS
                          TONS REMOVED
 Figure A-8.   Relevant Costs of Air Pollution  Disposal
                               137

-------
 once the  maximum welfare  condition  has been obtained  (see Figure A-9).
Through technological advances in air pollution control systems, society
will experience an effect that may be portrayed as a shift of the
marginal control cost curve to the right.  Such advancement is a classical
case of a technological effect.  Society benefits by a more efficient mode
of operatic^ that is, a net increase in productivity.
                                     138

-------
CO
o
I/)
8'
   B
   A
a:
                                   (MCC).
                                  (MCC),
                          -MARGINAL CONTROL COST
                         F  G
                         TONS REMOVED
  Figure A-9.
Reduction of the Relevant Costs of Air
Pollutant Disposal
                              139

-------
                                 APPENDIX B

          PRACTICAL MEASURES FOR OBSERVATIONS OF COSTS AND BENEFITS

      In the analysis of emission control strategies costs and benefits are
 plotted on rectangular coordinates for purposes of clarity (see Appendix C
 for illustrative plots of costs and benefits for alternative strategies).
 Control costs and benefits are normally plotted against some measure of
 pollution, with costs on the ordinate and the measure of pollution on the
 abscissa, as in the sketch below.
               COST($)
                                MEASURE OF POLLUTION(?)

      The measures of pollution which are most meaningful for the analysis
must be identified.  Some pollution measures which indicate the effective-
ness of control strategies are:
            •  Maximum concentration anywhere in the AQCR,
            •  Regional emission rate from point and area sources,
            •  Average concentration for all census tracts  in the AQCR,
               and
            •  Average concentration for the center city portion of the
               AQCR.
      Various other measures may also be used, but these four are adequate
as a beginning.
      The "maximum concentration" in an AQCR is now used by APCO to deter-
mine the acceptability of an emission control strategy.  Although this
measure is valuable as a means of ensuring that air quality is acceptable
at all points in an AQCR, it is not a good indicator of overall air quality,
Certain high-concentration points may remain unchanged, for example, while
overall regional air quality is improving.  Maximum concentration is thus
an inadequate measure for purposes of cost/benefit analysis.
                                            PRECEDING mi BLANK

-------
     The "emission rate" from sources in a region is a measure of the
total pollutant contribution and indicates the degree of emissions control.
Emission rate is not as closely related to benefits as is a measure of
region-wide air quality, but it does represent the effectiveness of source
control.  Typical emission rate data are shown in Figures B-l through B-4,
which plot tha costs and marginal control cost of strategies tested in the
NCIAQCR.
     Average "regional pollution concentration" (ARPC) is an excellent
indicator for cost/benefit analyses purposes,  since pollution concentra-
tion is the independent variable in damage functions.  ARPC is the
arithmetic average of predicted pollutant concentrations for all census
tracts in an AQCR.  Essentially, the measure is a weighted average rela-
tive to regional population.  In other words,  since the average census
tract contains approximately 4000 people, pollutant concentrations in
the area of greatest population density will be most heavily weighted.
     "Average center city pollution concentration" represents a compromise
between the "point of maximum concentration" and measures "regionwide aver-
age."  It is valuable as a measure of improvement in the zone of poorest
air quality.
     In summary, various "measures of pollution" are available for use as
the abscissa in C/B presentations, and a comparative analysis of the advan-
tages of these measures would be highly desirable.
                                    142

-------
     14 -
  X
     10
  o
  " 4 H
  o
  a.
     2 r
                                                       NOTE:  TOTAL EMISSIONS = POINT AND
                                                              AREA SOURCE EMISSIONS
EXISTING CONDITIONS
                      50              100            150            200
                        TOTAL PARTICULATE EMISSION RATE (TONS/DAY)
        *SEE TABLE B-l FOR DESCRIPTION OF PARTICULATE AND SULFUR DIOXIDE CONTROL STRATEGIES.
Figure B-l.   Point Source Control Cost vs..  Total Regional Particulate Emission Rate for
              NCIAQCR 	 for Selected Strategies

-------
                           Table B-l.

      SELECTED CONTROL STRATEGIES FOR THE NCIAQCR
                   Particulate Strategies
 1.   Existing Control Regulations Throughout the Region.   This
      strategy displays the air quality resulting from complete
      compliance with existing control-regulations in the  Region.

 2.   Maximum Control Technology.  Under this strategy the best
      available control device or measure (as defined in the Control
      Cost Model) is applied to each pollution source.  This
      strategy may be neither economically nor technically.feasible
      but does give a potential lower limit on pollutant emissions.

 3.   Existing Regulations in the District and Virginia -  No
      Emissions in Maryland.  Area source emissions were eliminated
      and point sources were substantially reduced by the  applica-
      tion of maximum control technology.
     •
18.   Proposed Particulate Control Strategy.  District of  Columbia
      sources were controlled to 0.03 grains/scf for industrial'
      process sources, 0.06 grains/scf fuel combustion and 0.20
      grains/scf for incineration.  Maryland and Virginia  sources
      were controlled to.the levels specified by their respective
      implementation plans.

                 Sulfur Dioxide Strategies

11.   Existing Regulations.  Complete application of existing regu-
      lations affecting sulfur oxide emissions throughout  the
      region.

12.   Maximum Control Technology.  The strategy requires the applica-
      tion of the best available control technology to all sources;
      in most cases, this requires fuel burning sources to switch
      to natural gas.

15.   Maximum of 0.7 Percent Sulfur Content Fuel in Region.   This
      gives a small reduction from the current 1.0 percent sulfur
      restriction now in effect in most of the Region.  (Major
      exceptions are the Dickerson and Chalk Point power plants.)

19.   Proposed Sulfur Oxide Control Strategy. A fuel sulfur content
      limitation of 0.5% was imposed on District of Columbia sources.
      Maryland and Virginia sources were controlled in accordance
      with their implementation plans."
                             144

-------
I 500  -


z
o

^ 450  -
o



~ 400




   350
1/1
o
S  300
ut
o
or
ra
o
t/i
    250
    200
5  150
on
    100



     50
Figure  B-2.
                        50              100            150            200

                   TOTAL REGIONAL  PARTICULATE  EMISSION RATE (TONS/DAY)

              Point Source Marginal Control Cost vs. Total  Regional  Particulate

              Emission Rate for NCIAQCR 	 for  Selected Strategies

-------
  110 -,
                                                NOTE:   TOTAL EMISSIONS =  POINT AND
                                                       AREA SOURCE EMISSIONS
                                                              500
600
                                                                                       EXISTING
                                                                                       CONDITIONS
700
                            TOTAL  SULFUR OXIDE  EMISSION RATE  (TONS/DAY)
       *SEE TABLE B-l FOR DESCRIPTION OF PARTICULATE AND SULFUR DIOXIDE CONTROL STRATEGY.


Figure  B-3.    Point Source Control Costs Vs.  Total Regional  Sulfur Oxide  Emission Rate
                         for NCIAQCR 	 for Selected  Strategies

-------
    700 -
n

 §600
 o  500
 o
   400 -
    300 -
 o
 0.
    200 -
    100 -
                   TOO
  I
300
 I
400
    200         300          400         500         600
TOTAL REGIONAL SULFUR OXIDE EMISSION RATE (TONS/DAY)
700
            Figure B-4.   Point Source Marginal Control Cost vs.  Total Regional Sulfur
                          Dioxide Emission Rate for NCIAQCR 	 for Selected Strategies

-------
                                APPENDIX C

               EFFICIENCY EVALUATIONS OF COSTS AND BENEFITS

     To illustrate the type of analysis which will be employed in economic
efficiency evaluations, some sample calculations and plots were prepared.
This exercise is presented here as an aid to understanding the relation-
ships that will be-encountered and as a stimulus to further analysis.  A
model region is used to illustrate efficiency evaluation procedures for
control costs and benefits.
                     EFFICIENCY EVALUATION EXERCISE
                                               AIR
Given:                                         QUALITY
                                               CONTROL
                                               RESIGN
                 PLANT A       ~
                                                PLANT B
     (1)  An air quality control region with two point sources,  Plant "A"
          and Plant "B"
     (2)  Control cost functions for a pollutant for each source
     (3)  Benefits for a pollutant for each source.   It is assumed that
          benefits have been determined by the use of a damage .function,
          where:.                             '      '      • •  .  •        •
            •  the function is linear (i.e.,  constant elasticity)
               for all concentrations.of the  pollutant,  i.e.,
               DAMAGE
               COST
                                               a + bx
                              POLLUTION CONCENTRATION
                                          PRECEDING PAKE BUNK

-------
            •  the function is curvilinear, i.e.,
               DAMAGE
               COST
                              POLLUTION CONCENTRATION
          and specific air quality conditions for the pollutant are given.
     (4)  Specific control strategies defined as follows: '
            •  Equi-Control Costs - all sources spend the 'same absolute
               .amount to control.
            •  Equi-Marginal Contrdl Costs - all sources spend the same
               absolute cost per ton removed to control.
            •  Equi-Tons Removed - all sources control the same absolute
               quantity of pollutant.
            •  Equi-Benefit - all sources control to a level where the
               benefits (on receptors) per source are identical.
            •  Equi-Marginal Benefit - all sources control to a level
               where the benefits (on receptors) per ton removed are
               identical for each source.
OBJECTIVES
     (a)  To examine the following relationships for each source:
            •  Control costs per ton removed
            •  Benefits per ton removed
            •  Marginal control costs per ton removed
            •  Marginal benefits per ton removed
            •  Benefit cost per ton removed
            •  (Marginal benefit/marginal cost) per ton removed
     (b)  To examine these same relationships for the air quality control
          region for each control strategy specified.
                                     150

-------
  DISCUSSION
       Figure C-l  illustrates control cost functions and benefit functions
  for the two autonomous plants (A and B).   These functions have been plotted
  against a "tons-removed" variable;  an "efficiency" variable could be used
  instead without changing the significance of the analysis.   It may be noted
  that the elasticity of the control  cost  function increases as a higher
                              .  §
  level of control is attained.   This observation is consistent with actual
  practice,  where more money m^.sr.be  spent.for each additional increment of
  emission control.  The elast  .cit;- of the  benefit function on the other hand
  decreases as emission cont-.  L .increases,  a fact which indicates that as
  ambient concentrations are  aduced  benefits increase at a declining rate.
       Figure C-2  relates m^.ginal control costs and marginal benefits as
  a function of  the quantity. . : p9llutants  removed.  These functions illus-
  trate the rate of change i^  -.ost for each incremental change of pollution
  control.   A point of Paret'.rCptiniality has been reached when one additional
                            f «, •
  dollar spent in improving pbmeone's welfare detracts proportionately from
  the welfare of another.   At'this point marginal costs equal marginal bene-
  fits.   In Figure C-2 , the rvtelfare".optimum for each source is reached at
                            . *< ,'*•
  the intersection of the  marginal control  cost curve and the marginal bene-
  fit curve.   This optimal position corresponds -to a level of just under 11
  tons removed per day for Plant A and 5.5  tons for Plant B.
                            i*
       The upper-graph in  Figure  G$3  shows the benefit/cost relationships
                              JJ^V*
  as  plotted against tons  remo^S^while the lower-graph portrays marginal
.. benefits  versus  marginal  costs^s ..p function of  tons removed.   As in Figure
  C-2 ,  the point  of  Pareto-optimality is  located  at  approximately 11 tons
  removed for  Plant A and 5.5  tons removed for Plant  B.   It  should be noted
  the  lesser the slope of the  marginal benefit versus marginal  cost function,
  the  less  significant it is for the  source to be  at  the exact  point of
  Pareto-optimality.   As  the slope of the  function approaches  the horizontal,
  the  source will  deviate less from  the optimum as the controls  slightly more
  or slightly  less.   As the slope of  the function  approaches the vertical,
  deviation from the  optimum welfare  position  will be more  significant as
  more or less pollution  is controlled.
      Table C-l illustrates the results of cost-benefit calculations at one
  level  of  control for alternative control strategies in an  AQCR with cwo
                                      151

-------
   15-
   10'
to
8
        PLANT A
                 BENEFITS
   15'
    10
8
        PLANT  B
                 BENEFIT:
                                  10
                             TONS REMOVED |,
15
                                   10
                             TONS REMOVED
IS
                                                         CONTROL
                                                         COSTS
20
20
 Figure C-l.    Control Cost and  Benefit Functions for Two  Plants
                                   152

-------
   3.001
                                      10

                                  TONS REMOVED
                                                                  MARGINAL
                                                                  CONTROL
                                                                  COST
          PLANT B
   2.00-
oo
O
O
   1.001
                                                       MARGINAL
                                                       CONTROL
                                                       COSTS
Figure C-2.
                                       10

                                   TONS REMOVED
                   Marginal Control Cost and Marginal Benefit Functions
                   for  Two Plants
                                   153

-------
MB/MC
                                 10
                           15

                         TONS REMOVED
20
     Figure C-3..
Benefit/Cose and Marginal Benefit/Cost
Plots for Two Plants
                               154

-------
                                                      Table  C-l
                                   COST-BENEFIT STRATEGY EVALUATIONS  	  EXAMPLES
Ul
STRAT.
Equi-
Control
Costs '
Equi-
Marginal
Control
Costs
Equi-
Tons
Removed
Equi- .
Benefits
Equi-
Marginal
Benefits
PLANT
A
B
TOTAL
A
B
TOTAL
A
B
TOTAL
A
B
TOTAL
. A
B
TOTAL
($)
CONTROL
COST
10.00
10.00
20.00
7.6
6.8
14.4
5.1
7.6
12.7
1.5
3.5
5.0
1.8
1.4
3.2
($/TON
MARGINAL
CONTROL COST
1.50
1.25
2.75
1.00
1.00
2.00
0.66
1.09
1.75
0.42
0.71
1.13
0.45
0.50
0.95
(TON)
REMOVED
17.5
13.7
31.2
15.5
11.0
26.5
12.00
12.00
24.00
5.0
6.5
11.5
6.0
3.3
9.3
$
BENEFITS
14.00
9.40
23.40
13.8
9.0
22.8
12.7
9.2
21.9
7.00
7.00
14.00
8.0
4.6
12.6
($/TON)
MARGINAL
BENEFITS
0.01
0.12
0.22
0.20
0.37
0.47
0.48
0.20
0.68
1.10
0.55
1.65
1.00
1.00
2.00
B/C
1.40
0.94
1.17
1.82
1.32
1.58
2.49
1.21
1.72
4.65
2.00
2.80
4.45
3.28
3.94
MB
MC
0.07
0.10
0.08
0.20
0.27
0.24
0.73
0.18
0.30
2.62
0.72
1.46
0.45
0.50
0.48
                 (MB)
(MC)
                 (MC)
(MC),

-------
sources.  The cost curves in Figure .C-l have been used in calculating
these results.  As may be seen, these control efficiencies vary from one
.strategy to another, and the relative efficiencies of the strategies cannot
be compared on the basis of these examples.
      The optimum level of control is illustrated in Figure C-4  for one
of the six strategies evaluated (the "equi-tons removed" strategy).   The
optimum reduction in emissions for the AQCR under this strategy is 13 tons
(each plant must thus remove 6-1/2 tons of emissions).  It should be noted
that the optimum situation occurs where:
            •  marginal costs equal marginal benefits, or, expressed in
               another way,
               marginal benefits/marginal cdgts equal unity.
                                     156

-------
 tO
 3
3 -
to
o^
<_) CO
       1  -
       3  '
to
t—
•-i tO
U- h-
UJ tO
z: O
UJ O
CO
*    i r  -
*-«/>!. 5
U. tO
UJ O
Z O
                                                REGIONAL TONS REMOVED
                                       MARGINAL
                                       CONTROL
                                       COSTS
                                                            MARGINAL BENEFITS
                                         20              30                40

                                                REGIONAL TONS  REMOVED
                                               REGIONAL TONS  REMOVED
                         10
                                  20                30
                                         REGIONAL  TONS REMOVED
                                                                          40
                                                                           00
                                                                           0)
                                                                           4J
                                                                           (0
                                                                                 10
                                                                          T)
                                                                          SI
                                                                          I
                                                                          
-------
                                APPENDIX D

                        CONTROL SUPPLIER FUNCTIONS

      Regional Air Pollution Analysis should include a provision for
examination of the additional economic activity experienced by suppliers
of equipment, services, and utilities to firms which are required to
control pollutant emissions.  The need for a control supplier function
became apparent in connection with the use of regional econometric
models to evaluate the impact of air pollution control measures on the
regional economy.  Economic impact is over-predicted for a region when
the activity needed to provide control devices and services is not taken
into consideration.
      Some of the investment in control systems will come from suppliers
in the region.  Services obtained from within a region may' include engi-
neering services for system design and installation, labor for construction
of foundations, metal .work, etc.  On the other hand, much of the hardware
(pumps, drives, etc.) will be imported from other locations, in which case
the firms that inventory and distribute the equipment within the region
will benefit.
      Most of the annual cost of controlling emissions will be spent on
services from the regional economy,   These will include water, electricity,
labor, hauling, and other services required to operate emission control
systems and dispose of the collected materials.
      Economic research is needed to determine the sectors which will
benefit from the demand for emission control equipment: and services  in and
outside the region.  The following procedure might be used in identifying
the value added for a region:
      Step 1.  Identify the categories of material and labor
               inputs to emission control systems according
               to:
               •   Pollutant
               •   Control system type
               •   Process-type

                                    .       PRECEDING PAGE BLANK

-------
  .Step 2.   Identify the categories of emission control systems within
           a region, which will Include:
           •  Turn-key
           •  Self-made
           •  Locally contracted, etc.
  Estimate the categories for the systems described in Step 1 on the
  basis of current Installations.  Also, project future installations.
  Step 3.   Categorize the elements of emission control systems.
           such as:
           • .Process takeoff
           •  Gas preconditioner
           •  Emission removal
           •  Gas postconditioner
           •  Gas moving
           •  Stack
           •  Emission disposal, etc.
  Step A.   identify for each system elements,-fdentified in Step 3 the
           investment categories, suotr as:
           •  Direct labor for Installation
           •  Hardware
           •  Sheet metal
           •  Concrete, etc.
  Step 5.   Identify for each system element^   listed in Step 3 the
           annual cost categories such as:
           •  Water
           •  Electricity
           •  Disposal charge
           •  Maintenance labor
                               •
           •  Repair labor
           •  Parts, etc.
  Step 6.   Determine whether the value added for control system invest-
           ment and annual costs is based inside or outside the AQCR.
  Step 7.   Prepare a matrix such as that shown in Figure D-l , which is
           similar to the control device matrix in the IPP program,1
Air Quality Implementation Planning Programming Vol. I, Operations
Manual, TRW Systems Group, McLean, Virginia, pp. 5-14 through 5-16,
1971.
                                 160

-------
REGION:



SOURCE
CATEGORY
SIC.
2040
SIC
2819
nnn 1
<
i /
SIC
2800
CONTROL
DEVICE
NO.
LOCATION
j**
A**
I
A
• Lfci
A
«
I
A

"VALUE ADDED" MIX
01
IN***




'•'
*



OUT









• i» it
IN



72*





OUT



28*





• / iii
IN






•


.OUT









45
IN









OUT

1




'


  *REPORTED  IN PERCENT

  **T    =  INVESTMENT
   A    =  ANNUAL  COST

***IN    =   "VALUE ADDED" CONTRIBUTION FROM INSIDE'THE AQCR
   OUT  =   "VALUE ADDED" CONTRIBUTION OUTSIDE THE AQCR
             Figure D-l.    Control Supplier Input  to  Cost/Benefit  Model
                                         161

-------
      Control supply  functions for .9our.ce .categories and  control system

types may be input  to the  C/R Model, so that^very ttme a point  source
                > S*           •'              . (.i J(i'..,.
is assigned a specific conjCffjJ^ defcice, the ,'VBlue added mix for the AQCR
(a ratio of.-internal  to- ex
1 value ad
for investment and  annual
costs) can be computed 'and  appl'ied in a econometric modeling.
                                                                      •V  *"•   ^^

                                                                      5  6  J
                                                                          CO   ^
                                                                          3
                                                                                   -
                                    162

-------