EPA-600/5-73-008b
October 1973
                        Socioeconomic Environmental Studies Series
  Research Needs and Priorities :
 Water  Pollution  Control  Benefits
  and  Costs -  Vol. II
                                         PRO
                                 Office of Research and Development
                                 U.S. Environmental Protection Agency
                                 Washington, D.C. 20460

-------
             RESEARCH REPORTING SERIES
Research  reports of the  Office  of   Research  and
Monitoring,   Environmental Protection Agency, have
been grouped into five series.  These  five  broad
categories   were established to facilitate further
development   and  application   of    environmental
technology.    Elimination  of traditional grouping
was  consciously  planned  to  foster   technology
transfer   and  a  maximum  interface  in  related
fields.   The five series are:

   1.  Environmental Health Effects  Research
   2.  Environmental Protection Technology
   3.  Ecological Research
   4.  Environmental Mcnitoring
   5.  Socioeconomic Environmental Studies

This report  has been assigned to the SOCIOECONOMIC
ENVIRONMENTAL   STUDIES   series.     This   series
describes research on the socioeconomic impact of
environmental problems.  This covers recycling and
other  recovery  operations   with    emphasis   on
monetary  incentives.  The non-scientific realms of
legal   systems,  cultural  values,   and  business
systems   are  also  involved.   Because  of  their
interdisciplinary  scope,  system  evaluations and
environmental management reports are  included  in
this series.
                      EPA REVIEW NOTICE
This report has been reviewed by the Office of Research and
Development, EPA, and approved for publication. Approval
does not signify that the contents necessarily reflect the
views and policies of the Environmental Protection Agency,
nor does mention of trade names or commercial products consti-
tute endorsement or recommendation for use.

-------
                                        £.fA-600/5-73-008b
                                        October 1973
    RESEARCH NEEDS AND PRIORITIES!
      WATER POLLUTION CONTROL
        BENEFITS AND COSTS
             VOLUME II
                 by

         David L. Jordening
          James K. Allwood
         Contract No. 68-01-0744
           Project 21-AQJ-05
         Program Element 1HA094
             Project Officer:

              Fred H. Abel
         Economic Analysis Branch
      Implementation Research Division
          Washington, D.C. 20460
              Prepared for
  OFFICE OF RESEARCH AND MONITORING
U.S. ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY
        WASHINGTON, D.C. 20460

-------
                             ABSTRACT
      This report includes foremost a specification; of research needs
 and priorities involving water pollution control costs and benefits.   A
 series of theoretical and methodological research needs are presented.
 Water quality management is required in a dynamic setting and over a
 broad range of hydrologic and economic conditions.  The common
 property resource aspects of the problem with the  prevalence of exter-
 nalities complicates the issues involved.  These and  other factors em-
 bedded in the research needs are discussed.

      A major  development of a cost-minimization methodological
 approach for water quality management is also presented.  Within this
 framework the indicated research needs are more  readily identified
 and explained.

      An important distinction is made between the economic costs of
 pollution and the costs of pollution abatement.  The economic costs  of
 pollution such as damages, efficiency reductions,  increased production
 expenses, process changes and opportunity costs are a function of
 water quality,  whereas pollution abatement  costs are typically a func-
 tion of the degree of pollution control.  For comparable cost compari-
 sons, a transformation of pollution abatement costs in terms of water
 quality is desired.  This transformation need  and problem is discussed
 in detail.

      Finally,  in a series of technical appendicies, the following
 subjects are discussed:

      (1)  water pollution control cost and benefit estimates,
      (2)  water quality associated health impacts,
      (3)  specific pollutant sources,  damages and potential
          treatment methods,  and
      (4)  critical levels  and damage threshholds for  selected pollutants.

      This report was submitted in fulfillment of Project Number
21-AQJ-05,  Contract Number  68-01-0744 by Development Planning  and
Research Associates, Inc. ,  Manhattan, Kansas, under the sponsorship
of the Environmental Protection Agency.  Work was completed as of
May,  1973.
                                  11

-------
                        CONTENTS

                                                             Page

Abstract                                                      ii

Exhibits                                                      iv

Acknowledgments                                              vi

Executive Summary                                           vii

Sections

I      Background Perspectives and Research Needs            1

II      A General Methodological Approach                     30

III     Economic Cost of Pollution                             63

IV     Cost of Pollution Abatement                            78

V      Estimating Water Quality as a Function of Pollution
       Control                                                83

VI     Conclusions and Direction of Future Work               119

VII    Appendices                                             125
                            111

-------
                         EXHIBITS

No.                                                          Page

II-1    Benefits of pollution abatement measures in the
       Ohio River Valley in the various uses of the surface
       water                                                   37

II-2    Annual costs and benefits of water pollution abate-
       ment measures                                         38

II-3    Effect of degree of removal of dissolved organic mat-
       ter from effluents on annual costs and economic bene-
       fits due to pollution abatement in the Maumee River
       Basin                                                  40

II-4   Treatment processes that can be costed by the waste-
       water treatment plant cost estimating program          44

II-5   Cost of treatment and degree of control (by treatment
       strategy)                                               45

II-6   Water quality and percent treatment                     48

II-7   Economic  costs of pollution                             50

II-8   Total water quality benefits                             52

II-9   Total cost of waste disposal                             60

III-l  Beneficial use classifications and specific impacts
       of water pollution                                       65

III-2  Economic  costs of pollution                             68

III-3  Economic  cost of pollution in reference to municipal
       preuse treatment                                       72

III-4  Recreation participation variables                       74

IV-1  Total capital,  operating and maintenance costs re-
       quired to meet current standards in 1968 and 1976       81

 V-l    Effect of degree of removal of dissolved organic
        matter from effluents on annual costs and economic
        benefits due to pollution abatement in the Maumee
                                                                84
        River Basin

                              iv

-------
                   EXHIBITS (continued

No.                                                          Page

V-2    Selected water quality characteristics                    87

V-3    Drinking water standards of the U.S. Public Health
       Service, 1962                                           88

V-4    Classification of water quality according to hardness
       and salinity properties                                  90

V-5    Assessment of surface water quality by a single
       index of pollution                                        91

V-6    Battelle's Environmental Evaluation System              92

V-7    Components of the PDI water quality measurement
       system                                                 97

V-8    Total assimilative capacity of streams of different
       orders                                                  99

V-9    Sources of surface water pollutants                     100

V-10  Variations in dissolved solids and  sediment concen-
       trations in major river basins in arid and semiarid
       United States                                           103

V-ll  Water quality characteristics adopted for this study     107

V-12  General form of surface water quality  - degree of
       control curves                                         109

V-13  Raw and treated effluent flows, illustrative case         112

V-14  Surface water quality as a function of effluent load,
       BOD by quarter of year,  illustrative example           115

V-15  BOD content of treated effluent as  a function  of
       degree of treatment, illustrative case                   116

-------
                    ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
       This report represents a group effort.  Various Environ-
mental Protection Agency (EPA) and Development Planning and
Research Associates,  Inc. (DPRA) personnel were involved and
our thanks  goes to all who directly participated.

       The EPA Economic Analysis Branch staff in general, but
especially  Fred Abel,  Chief and Dennis Tihansky, project liaison
representative, assisted by providing  information and direction to
the study.

       Many DPRA staff members and associates contributed to
this  report.  James Allwood and David Jordening shared respon-
sibility for preparing this report.  Donald Wissman and Samuel
Unger provided economic assistance and support. We, as econ-
omists, express our appreciation for support of Larry Erickson
and M. Y.  Chow who provided "engineering" inputs.  We also
recognize the assistance provided by Jarvin Emerson, Arlo Biere
and Linda Erickson during the early stages of this second phase of
study. The diligence and understanding of Frances Moyer and Eloise
Bourque who provided secretarial support in preparing draft and final
materials is acknowledged.  The most helpful assistance of Karen
Huff who "computerized" and  key-worded our massive reference
list is duly recognized as is the diligence of Mike Woolverton and
others who assisted in reviewing the literature.

       Finally, we wish to thank those authors who have shared their
thoughts, findings and hypotheses with us through the printed media.
Without their contributions, this undertaking would have been im-
possible.

-------
                   EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
       The principal objectivei of this report is to specify research
needs and priorities involving water pollution control costs and
benefits.  In addition, a major extension toward development of
a cost-minimization methodological approach for water quality
management is presented.

       Research needs and priorities are based both on a state-of-
the-art review and a  critical evaluation of methodologies and ap-
proaches to water quality management which have been used.  Further,
the research needs and priorities can be formulated only when an
adequate analytical framework and general technique has been
selected.   Such a framework, limited to partial equilibrium analysis
techniques, is presented in Section II.

       In summary,  this  report is divided into six sections.

       I.        Background Perspectives and Research Needs
       II.       A General Methodological Approach
       III.      Economic Cost of Pollution
       IV.      Cost of Pollution Abatement
       V.       Estimating Water Quality as a Function of Pollution
                Control
                                          \
       VI.      Conclusions and Directions of Future Work

       Section I reviews the state-of-art findings (Part I) plus addi-
tional partial equilibrium approaches.  A critical evaluation of existing
work is made and research needs and priorities are stated.  Section II
presents and recommends a partial equilibrium technique for  future
use.  Sections III, IV and V are needed  extensions arising from the
methodological approach adopted in Section II.   The  final section pre-
sents general conclusions and outlines some specific areas of study
which are proposed for further  consideration by EPA. In addition,
a series of appendices are included and referenced in the report.

I.   Background Perspectives and Research Needs

       There is evidence of considerable lack of direction and co-
ordination in water quality management literature.   In most cases it
can be said that water quality management literature is at the infancy
stage.  There is also the failure on the  part of many to recognize the
common property resource aspects of water quality management
                              VII

-------
which is the primary source of environmental quality problems.  This
inevitably leads to a symptomatic approach to the problem rather than
a direct confrontation of the major factors involved in the water qual-
ity management problem.

        Many of the partial equilibrium studies are  either high
project-problem-crisis oriented or consider only a very small
portion of the total first round or primary impacts  of water qual-
ity deterioration.

        The approaches to the water quality management problem
can be segmented into two broad categories based on the level at
which they address the problem,  i.e. , general equilibrium as
opposed to partial equilibrium analysis/

        There is considerable controversy in the literature covering
the proper theoretical approach to be utilized in assessing water
quality associated impacts.  Both the general equilibrium and partial
equilibrium approaches have their own respective strengths and limi-
tations.  The quest for immediate answers and the  many uncertainties
associated with water quality management necessitates adopting a
readily accessible pragmatic approach to the problem.  In this regard
partial equilibrium methods must be selected,  duly recognizing the
inherent limitations.

          Methodological and Theoretical Research Needs

       A series of general methodological and theoretical research
needs  are presented.  Water quality management is required  in a
dynamic setting and over a broad  range of hydrologic and economic
conditions.  The common property resource aspects of the problem
with the prevalence of externalities complicates the issues involved.
These and other factors are  embedded in the  general research needs.

       Some general methodological and  theoretical research needs
(not listed in order of priority) include:

        1.  Development of methods and procedures to identify
           and quantify water associated  benefit and cost functions
           relating specific benefits and costs to specific pollutants.
                             Vlll

-------
 2.   Development of economic and hydrologic models to
     identify and quantify complex intra- and interbasin
     relationships.

 3.   Extension and refinement of accounting measures,
     such as "insurance values," for uncertain water
     quality associated costs and benefits.

 4.   Formulation of a measure of value that can be used as
     a common denominator additive measure  to effectively
     evaluate all intangible and indirect nonmonetary costs
     and benefits associated with changes in water quality.

 5.   Development of alternative pollution abatement policies
     designed to minimize undesirable equity and distribu-
     tion impacts  associated with water quality control.

 6.   Quantification of complex water quality substitution
     effects.  As water quality deteriorates, certain substi-
     tution effects may be expected.

 7.   Development of an aggregation framework to assess
     regional and national pollution control costs and benefits.

 8.   Assessment of alternative political,  legal and institu-
     tional arrangements needed to perform water pollution
     control management functions.

 9.   Development of procedures to project and evaluate
     alternative distributions of benefits and costs through
     time, i.e., "time profiles," including the use of a social
     discount rate to compute present value.

10.   Estimation of net social benefits attributable to water
     pollution control measures, i.e., measurement of a
     social welfare function. Water pollution  control
     measures are expected to impact economic structures
     with consequent relative shifts in supply and demand
     relationships.  Such consequences call for analysis of
     the social welfare function.
                         IX

-------
       The above list includes a variety of methodological and
theoretical research needs, some of which suggest that a substantial
reassessment of commonly held social objectives is in order.
                       Data Input Needs

       The solution of water quality management problems cannot
be satisfactorily pursued until  a comprehensive understanding of
natural and physical relationships has been achieved and quantified.
The absence  of such data input at the present time limits the ac-
curacy of comprehensive national benefit and cost function that may
be developed.

        Some of the physical,,  chemical, biologica;!, economic and
 engineering data input needs include, but are not limited to, the
 following items:

        1.  Relationships between waste treatment cost and effluent
            water quality for each pollutant and for each type of in-
            dustrial and  municipal wastes.

        2.  The quantity of each pollutant from  non-point sources
            which enters each receptor.

        3.  The extent of assimilation of each pollutant by natural
            processes  in each receptor.

        4.  The effect  of each pollutant on municipal and industrial
            water treatment processing costs where surface waters
            are used for  municipal and  industrial water supplies.

        5.   The effects of untreated pollutants on industrial and
            domestic activities.

       6.   The effect of each  pollutant on fish and wildlife  support
            capabilities.

        7.  The relationships  between recreational usage and
            water quality,  i.e., contact and noncontact water
            based recreational demand  and water quality.

-------
       8.  Effects of each pollutant on the useful life of each
           reservoir and lake.

       9.  Effects of each pollutant on health.

      10.  Effects of each pollutant on final receptors such as
           Lake Erie, Gulf of Mexico and oceans.

      11.  Establishment of regional functions relating  degree
           of treatment and resulting water quality.
                       Specific Priorities

       The state of the arts review has uncovered many specific
areas and tasks that need to be substantially extended if an^equi-
table solution to the water quality management problem is to be
achieved.  The most critical of the  needs and priorities are
summarized below. A more comprehensive listing is included in
Section I of the text.

       1.   Development and implementation of appropriate method-
            ology and procedures capable of providing direction and
            guidance in an area that has typically been problem -
            project-crisis oriented. This may well be accomplished
            by extending and refining the priority listings and bene-
            fit matrices presented in Appendix A.

       2.   Further development of appropriate water quality associ-
            ated methodologies including items such as substitution
            effects, relationships between treatment  and resulting
            water quality,  aggregation procedures and inter-basin
            relationships.

       3.   Further development, extension and application of pro-
            cedures capable of assessing ecological,  esthetic and
            recreation associated water quality impacts.
                               XI

-------
II*   A Methodological Approach

       Preliminary examination indicates that health, production
and municipal uses cannot be considered to be the source of
large benefits of water quality improvement.  It appears that the
only way pollution abatement measures can be justified in a bene-
fit cost framework is through the accurate assessment of recre-
ation and esthetic benefits -- which are not possible at the present
time.

        With the present inability to accurately measure and assess
 intangible and indirect benefits, the question  arises of how to best
 serve the  true social objectives.  This can be accomplished more
 directly by casting water quality management in an alternative con-
 ceptual framework --a cost minimization approach.  Costs include
 both treatment costs and damage costs,  e. g.  , damages,  efficiency
 reductions and opportunity costs.

       Since the primary source of the pollution problem stems
from externalities or avoidance of on-site costs, the proper
approach is to consider and minimize all costs (both  on-site and
off-site).  The off-site (economic costs of pollution) vary inversely
with the level of water  quality.   In the total absence of control the
economic costs of pollution are at a maximum and at total control
the economic costs are at zero {Exhibit 1).  The second component
of total social cost of pollution  is the cost of pollution abatement as
shown at the zero level with no controls in place and increasing as
controls are enforced.   The social objective can be maximized by
selecting the water quality level which minimizes the total water
disposal cost such as point A in the Exhibit.
III.  Economic Cost of Pollution
       The economic cost of pollution involves multidimensional
components.  Economic costs are dependent on, for example,  spe-
cific beneficial water uses,  specific pollutants involved and geo-
graphic location.  This requires disaggregation of the problem in
order to derive useful economic cost estimates.  Further, then,
aggregation schemes are necessary to derive national economic
cost estimates and functions.
                                XU

-------
Exhibit 1.    Total cost of waste disposal.
                                            Total cost
                                               Economic cost of
                                               pollution abatement
                                      Economic cost of pollution
                                             Water Quality Characteristics
                            Xlll

-------
        Four broad areas of beneficial water use are health,  pro-
 duction, esthetics and ecology.  Specific kinds of impact of water
 pollution among various  beneficial use classifications are pre-
 sented.  The types of economic cost which may occur are damages,
 efficiency reductions,  process changes,  added expenses and oppor-
 tunity costs.

        Estimation procedures for estimating economic costs of
 pollution are discussed.   An example of the cost of municipal
 preuse water treatment in relation to alternative levels of water
 quality is discussed.  From this relationship the economic cost of
 pollution (damage) is  derived. Other examples of estimation of
 economic costs are cited.
 IV.   Cost of Pollution Abatement

        Procedures for establishing regional or national cost of
 pollution abatement functions are summarized and limiting factors
 noted.  Current data and extensions (Appendix A) are then used to
 generate national pollution abatement cost estimates for  all munici-
 pal and industrial  secondary water treatment.  On an annualized
 basis, national pollution abatement cost estimates are $3. 9 billion
 for 1968 and $4.6 billion for 1976.   These estimates include total
 capital,  operating and maintenance costs (in 1967 dollars) required
 to meet  standards for 1968 and 1976, respectively.
 V.   Estimating Water Quality as a Function of Pollution Control

        The economic costs (damages, etc.) of pollution are a function
 of water quality whereas pollution abatement costs are typically a
 function of degree of pollution control.  A transformation of pollution
 abatement costs in terms of water quality is desired for  comparable
 cost comparisons.  However,  numerous measures of water quality
 are available including physical,  chemical, biological and esthetic
 properties.

                    Measuring Water Quality

       Problems encountered in measuring water quality are out-
lined and different measurement systems are discussed.   Given a
                                xiv

-------
set of water quality measurements, it is still necessary to classify
these measurements  to rank the quality of water.  Selected classi-
fication systems for water quality are also described.

                 Determinants of Water Quality

       A primary determinant of quality is the quantity and type
pollutants entering a  water receptor,  but of equal importance is the
inherent waste-assimilative capacity  of surface water.  Consider-
ation of composite  relationships are therefore required.

       A variety of sources of surface water pollutants, i.e.,
meterologic,  domestic,  industrial and agricultural, are discussed,
as are the major quality impacts of each.

           Measuring Water Pollution Control Levels

       Conventional means of measuring or  classifying the degree
of pollution control has created some methodological problems toward
estimation of  water quality.   Most frequently degree of pollution con-
trol is stated  as a percentage or proportion of one or more pollutants
removed from effluent flows.  Absolute measures of raw effluent
flows (including concentrations) into surface waters must be made,
however,  if water quality  estimate's are to be derived.

                          Aggregation

       Measurement of either water quality  or degree of pollution
control involves a variety of  aggregation problems.   Spatial distri-
butions of water, temporal aspects (including seasonal flows within
a year), the nature and variability of  wasteflows,  and variations in
treatment facility-effectiveness are among the problems  encountered
when aggregating water quality and degree of pollution control
measures.

       Water quality indexes tend to compound aggregation problems.
A conclusion  for this study is that water quality should be measured
via specific pollutant values rather than an index.
                              xv

-------
                  Recommended Approach

       An approach is recommended for relating degree of pollution
control to water quality within a  national water pollution control
assessment framework based upon partial equilibrium and short-
run planning constraints.

       The  recommended approach is illustrated for a case study
from secondary (plus hypothesized) data.  Tranformation curves
and functions are shown.

       The  transformation functions developed are shown to  shift
over time assuming increased economic activity and population
growth.  The result is an expected increase in degree  of treatment
to maintain  the same level of water quality.  Because of the higher
cost of improved degrees of treatment (constant technology assumed),
the maintenance of a given level  of water quality becomes more diffi-
cult to economically justify over time (constant per capita benefits
also assumed).  These latter conditions are readily identifiable
using the degree of control/water quality transormation approach
developed.

VI.  Conclusions and Directions  of Needed  Study

       The  final chapter first presents  a series of general conclusions.
Also presented are selected possible areas of emphasis for .continued
work.  Three areas of research  recommended for immediate emphasis
are briefly as follows:

       1.   Development of methodology to assess such problem areas as<
                 a.  Substitution effects
                 b.  Treatment versus quality transformation functions
                 c.  Aggregation schemes.

       2.   Refinement of pollutant/receptor benefit matrix relation-
            ships (as initially developed in Appendix A) to better achieve
            priority rankings of areas requiring the greatest attention.

       3.   Development of procedures and methodologies to identify
            and quantify ecological, esthetics and recreational benefit
            impacts of water pollution control.
                            xvi

-------
  Appendix A;  Appraisal of Cost of Control and Benefit Estimates

         A special effort was made to develop specific benefit and
  cost estimates and  related information as presented in Appendix A.
  This appendix concentrates on:  (1) municipal and industrial pollu-
  tion abatement costs (nonpoint sources were not included), (2) the
  relative importance of a series  of beneficial water uses, and (3)
  the  relative importance of various specific pollutants.
      Municipal and Industrial Pollution Abatement Costs

       Estimates of wasteflows, concentrations and wasteloads
are presented for 1968 under no treatment,  prevailing treatment
and current standards treatment assumptions.  Even with 100 per-
cent compliance with current standards, substantial quantities of
pollution would be contained in treated effluents.

       Abatement capital costs for 1968 flow conditions are estim-
ated as:  (1967 constant dollars)

       a.   prevailing levels -- over $14 billion
       b.   current standards in 1968 -- nearly $26 billion ,

Estimated 1976 costs for full compliance (in 1967 constant dollars)
are over $30 billion capital replacement value and $4. 5 billion
annual costs (including annual capital cost).


              Importance of Beneficial Water Uses

       Past studies indicate benefits are distributed as follows
(ignoring health, ecological,  intangible esthetics and agricultural
irrigation):

                                                 Percent of
              Beneficial use                     total benefits
       Municipal preuse treatment               2.6 - 28.9
       Domestic use                               0 - 31.7
       Industrial use                             3.5 - 21.6
       Navigation                                  0 -  2.8
       Commercial fishing                          0. 0
            Total production                     17.3 - 75.9
       Recreation                               23.0 - 77.8
       Property values                          1.2 - 21.8
            Total tangible esthetics              24.1 - 82.7
                                xvii

-------
         The above benefit distributions reflect recreation benefits in
 total before substitution effects.  Adjusting for this factor by assuming
 50 percent would be left after substitution and by estimating the rela-
 tive magnitudes  of the beneficial uses ignored in those studies, DPRA
 developed the following subjective estimates of benefit distributions:
                                                 Percent of
              Beneficial use                     total benefits
       Health                                     4. 0  -  4.5
       Production
           Municipal preuse treatment           10.0  - 12.0
           Domestic  use                         12.5  - l4.0
           Industrial use                         8.5  - 11.5
           Irrigation &t animal health             3.0-4.0
           Navigation                            0.5  -  1.5
           Commercial fishing                       0. 1
               Total                              37. 1  - 40.6
       Tangible esthetics
           Recreation                           17.0  - 18.5
           Property values                       1.5  -  2.0
               Total                              18.5  - 20.5

       Ecological & intangible esthetics          36.9  - 37.9

       Expansions of  the benefit distributions to national estimates
of total social welfare benefits were not attempted due to state-of-
data limitations and methodological considerations.

       In terms of research  priorities,  we rank the  beneficial uses
as follows with the most important first;

       1.  Ecological and intangible esthetics
       2.  Recreation
       3.  Municipal preuse treatment
       4.  Domestic  use
       5.  Industrial use
       6.  Health
       7.  Agricultural irrigation and animal health
       8.  Property values
       9.  Navigation
      10.  Commercial fishing.
                               XVlll

-------
         This ranking is based both on percentage distribution of
 benefits and pollutant damage  potential considerations.  To assist
 in this task, a pollutant-beneficial use damage potential matrix
 was developed to reflect known and suspected pollutant-use rela-
 tionships.
                Importance of Specific Pollutants

       Based upon a percentage benefit weighted pollutant-beneficial
use damage potential matrix and subjective estimates of national
pollution prevalence and intensity by specific pollutant,  research
priorities were subjectively ranked as:

       1.   Organics -- BOD, COD
       2.   Nutrients -- nitrogen, phosphates
       3.   Suspended and dissolved solids
       4.   Turbidity, pH,  temperature
       5.   Fecal coliforms, oil, toxic substances, floating solids,
            color,  odor
       6.   Hardness, taste, radioactivity.
                               xix

-------
                        SEC TION I

  BACKGROUND PERSPECTIVES AND RESEARCH NEEDS


A.   Introduction

       This document summarizes developments for the second
part of a three-phased program of study:

       Phase I:      State-of-Art Review
       Phase II:     Specification of Research Needs and Priorities
       Phase III:     Selected Implementation Research

A separate state-of-the-art literature review report (4) was pre-
sented summarizing various methodologies and procedures that
have been developed and utilized in assessing the economics of
water quality management.

       The objectives of this segment of the project are to (1)
establish research needs and priorities for estimating benefit and
co st-of-control functions relative to policy needs--independent of
data and methodology contraints,  (2) to establish research needs and
priorities for estimating benefit and cost-of-control functions rela-
tive to policy needs--given data and methodology constraints, (3) to
further analyze and evaluate selected studies that have undertaken
the formulation of area water quality associated benefit cost esti-
mates  or functions, (4) to  further supplement and refine water
quality associated benefit cost methodology, (5) to explore alter-
native  procedures that may be more appropriate  to the water qual-
ity management problem and (6) to suggest possible areas to be
emphasized in future research.

        The above objectives represent a considerable extension
beyond the intended effort.  This, however, is  an inevitable by-
product of the formulation of research needs and priorities and
the detailed assessment of the relative merits of existing work.
The state-of-the-arts must be followed by a critical evaluation.

-------
   Both tasks, i.e. , state-of-the-arts review and a critical evaluation,
   are requisite inputs in the development of research needs and the
   assignment of research priorities. Further, the  research needs
   and priorities can be formulated only when an adequate analytical
   framework or general  technique has been selected,  developed or
   as in this case,  refined.

          To successfully accomplish the above objectives, it is
   expedient to first outline the primary management problem; and,
   second, to evaluate the contributions and relative  merits of existing
   work beyond the state-of-the-arts presentation.  Complementary
   research needs and priorities are subsequently formulated.
 B.  Primary Resource Management Problem

        The primary problem or shortcoming of the present system
 from which almost all environmental problems emanate is the in-
 ability of the market system to efficiently allocate  common property
 resources (this includes the temporal allocation of resources).  This
 deficiency is inherently tied to the concept that certain resources
 are not owned individually but considered free.  Title is acquired
 only through capture (fugitive  resources).

        This notion of free resources implicitly means that the
 market system does  not and is not capable of placing a value on
 these resources.  Efficient allocation and utilization  of such re-
 sources  may be difficult in the absence of market prices or private
 efficiency incentives. In some cases the  present social system
 actually encourages inefficient allocation  and utilization of resources.
 Individuals mining groundwater in areas anticipating  pumping re-
 strictions based on historical usage, for example,  are encouraged
 to extract resources  beyond the point of positive net marginal value
 in an attempt to protect  future pumping privileges.  Further,  a
 variety of studies have established that industrial water users  are
 seldom charged a price  for water which is equal to the marginal
 cost of providing water or the  marginal costs of contaminating the
water.  (1)

-------
        While these.examples are related to quantity rather than
quality aspects of the problem, both issues are part of the broader
resource allocation question and serve to reinforce the fact that
private incentives governing efficient resource use and allocation
are not provided by the market mechanism or any other outside
source. Some have been tempted to summarize the problem with
one word--externalities.  While this is perhaps an overstatement
the inte rnalization of all water quality associated costs and benefits
would  eliminate a substantial portion of the problem.  It must be
emphasized that  externalities  are actually the result and not the
source of the problem.

        In the absence  of efficient market allocations,  proper cor-
rective measures must be implemented.  This means  that some
socially responsible agency (presumably the  Federal government)
is beseiged with  the problem of either revising the market system
to encourage efficient common property resource utilization or of
providing adequate incentives  exogenous of the market system.

        Proponents of the market system have historically advo-
cated the merits  of the former approach.  Others,  recognizing
the difficulties of such an undertaking have recommended the
latter.  The  source of the incentive is beyond the scope of this
section. However, it is recognized  that some attempts must be
made to account  for this deficiency if the water quality management
problem is to be  solved.  It should be further recognized that the
difficulty encountered in either approach is that of developing a
policy or framework that produces optimum  results, i.e., over-
pricing or underpricing effluents would  not produce socially optimum
results, thereby  adding little to the solution  of the overall problem.

        While the complexities and complications are great and the
alternatives are  many, a slight digression into specific attempts
to provide the financial incentive inherently lacking in the market
mechanism will further illuminate the basic  problem.

        Since the  postulation extended is that the market system
fails to include all costs of production (externalities) including
waste disposal, a financial penalty that  makes it at least as ex-
pensive to dump  untreated waste into the environment  as it is to
pay for waste treatment should contribute to  environmental cleanup.
Operationally, the financial penalty may be in the form of a fine,

-------
 a tax on the end product, or a system of charges of so much per
 ton of waste discharged. Financial rewards  (subsidies) for waste
 treatment are the reverse of penalties and are similar from an
 analytical viewpoint.


        Fines or threat of fines are frequently used to enforce
 compliance with environmental standards. Fines with or with-
 out an injunction that forces closure can be severe enough to
 accomplish the objective of waste cleanup.  This alternative does
 have disadvantages.  First, the fine comes after the  fact.  Not
 only does  excessive pollution occur but considerable  delay maybe
 expected before action is taken to remedy the situation.  Litigation
 proceedings are never swift and the growing list promises to be
 both expensive and time consuming. Also, fines probably create
 more  ill will than any other procedure.  No one likes to be publicly
 censored or forced to endure court proceedings which question
 innocence. Fines can therefore be expected  to lose as many
 friends of environmental causes as are won.

        A tax  becomes a more desirable alternative.  Admittedly,
 it is difficult  to estimate the amount of tax needed and it often has
 the added disadvantage of administrative complexity and expense.
 But the greatest impact of a per unit tax is on the consumption of a
 product whose production (and ultimate disposal) causes  many of
 our environmental problems.  Use of a tax on the consumer product
 or resources  used in its production leads to a smaller quantity taken
 by consumers and simultaneously provides revenue for environmental
 c leanup.

        Perhaps the most desirable financial penalty would be a sur-
 charge or tax levied directly on the polluter discharging waste into
 the air or water.  By levying a charge  on waste in excess of "normal
 levels," business firms have an economic incentive to reduce the
 amount of water or air carried waste,  thereby relieving the load on
 treatment plants.  As an example of its effectivenessi a  surcharge
 of 8  cents per pound of BOD in the city of Durham, North Carolina
 resulted in internal plant changes to bring about a 70  percent reduc-
tion in daily waste discharge.  (2. )  Further, it is an efficient alternative
 in that the worst offenders pay the largest share of abatement cost
while the tax is small to those who have already attempted  to reduce
waste.

-------
        The charge method can, through a series of approximations,
be set to bring about a specified stream or air standard.  A charge
also brings continuous pressure to update waste technology.  Its
effects are felt at all levels  of waste discharge where a standard
may be set to bring no change to minimum level polluters or pro-
vides no incentive for change below the required level.  The  charge
is desirable from an economic view in that firms recognize it as
a cost of doing business and adjust to it on a marginal basis.

        Even though a tax system levied on an individual point-by-
point discharge basis  would  be quite expensive to enforce and ad-
minister,  that objection could be largely overcome by an across-
the-board  tax schedule applicable to all who discharge into a par-
ticular stream or air quality control region.


       Environmental objectives may also be met by offering finan-
cial rewards rather than penalties.  A  subsidy for environmental
cleanup could be any of several types.  An investment tax credit
or favorable depreciation schedule could be  sufficient incentive to
invest in equipment to reduce waste.  Grants or tax credits could
be employed to induce use of recycled materials while favorable
credit terms to cities  could pay for water and sewer facilities.
Although the ^ist of fiscal techniques could be  extensive, the common
thread is meeting environmental cleanup objectives at public  expense
rather than the expense of business firms or local governments.

       Subsidizing environmental cleanup carries distinct dis-
advantages.  Of first importance, the worst offenders are those
most  rewarded and therefore the subsidy is  objectionable on equity
grounds.  The prospect of receiving a public subsidy will frequently
delay abatement programs until all avenues  to the grant are exhausted.
In fact, the subsidy alone does not guarantee cleanup.  The polluter
may choose not to take advantage of the lower cost, especially if
there will be a large outlay in addition to the subsidy.  Since  the
subsidy is  not paid directly by the consumer of the final product
there is no decline in quantity taken or no change in relative price
of the product.  While a charge may lead the business firm to make
optimal adjustments to reduce waste discharge, with subsidy schemes,
there is no comparable incentive to choose production methods that
lead to less waste and there  could be encouragement to do the opposite.
Finally, financial penalties yield revenue while subsidies are a drain
on the public treasury which must be defended each time budget ap-
proval is discussed.

-------
       The aboVte material reiterates the need to provide financial
incentives  (endogenous or exogenous of the market system) into
common property allocation and also provides several examples
of such attempts. While  it is not an exhaustive list of corrective
measures, it is illustrative of attempts to solve the pollution problem
by attaching  the source of the problem, i.e. ,  the introduction of exo-
genous financial  incentives to provide the impetus to efficiently allo-
cate and utilize common property resources.

       It further emphasizes that the primary source  of the pollution
problem can be traced back to the lack of a complete market system.
Additional research is needed to develop and explore various alter-
natives to alleviate this intrinsic deficiency.   We have no allusion in
respect to the magnitude  of the task proposed nor are we suggesting
that this be the first undertaking.  There is no doubt,  however, that
the problem  is bound in these terms and an effective and lasting solu-
tion cannot be  reached without directly facing these issues.  To this
end we merely state that all other problems are secondary to this
primary problem of common property resource allocation and  that
the long run  needs do  not necessarily have the highest priority in the
short run. It does appear, however,  that a great deal of effort has
been expended in a symptomatic treatment of pollution problems with-
out recognition of the  basic problem.
C.  Critical Evaluation and jSummary of Existing Water
    Quality Management  Literature

       For the purposes  of the following discussion,  the evaluation
of water quality associated models and procedures  shall proceed on
the  following basis:

       (1)  Evaluation on a theoretical basis
       (2)  Evaluation on an implementational basis
       (3)  Summary statement

-------
Evaluation on a Theoretical Basis

       The evaluation of economic models and procedures associ-
ated with water quality management on a theoretical basis could
lead far  afield by attempting to discuss the intricacies of a large
number of specific models.  The desire here is  to provide a general
summary evaluation on a theoretical basis and such temptations must
therefore be avoided by developing an alternative delineating criteria
other than numerous theoretical and methodological considerations
of specific models.

       One such delineating criteria is to segment the approaches
into two  broad categories based on the level at which they address
the water quality management problem, i.e.,  general equilibrium
as opposed to partial equilibrium analysis.  For the present pur-
poses this distinction is more manageable and meaningful than
delving into specific methodologies, procedures and assumptions
of specific models.  This taxonomy is further desirable for present
purposes in that all approaches are,  by definition,  either general
or partial in nature, thereby providing a natural circumscription
for the general summary that follows.  The basic distinction is
that the partial equilibrium, models consider only a subset of the
total problem while the general equilibrium models are concerned
with the  problem in its entirety (including secondary as well as
primary impacts as they a'ffect the total area or national economy).
                 General Equilibrium Analysis
       The general equilibrium methods discussed in Phase I in-
cluded the following specific models and types of models:

       (1)  Material-Process-Product Models
       (2)  Ecologic-Economic Models
       (3)  Kneese Model
       (4)  Input-Output Models,  and
       (5)  Systems Analysis

       These models, as well as  other  general equilibrium models,
have the advantage of placing the water  quality management problem
in its proper conceptual setting by considering the entire problem
with all of its various  interactions. The problem is normally viewed

-------
in a highly aggregated framework perhaps even to the point of con-
sidering welfare maximization objectives involving social (public)
choice and public decision making.  This general approach is further
intuitively pleasing in that it is consistent and compatible with the
approaches to welfare maximization in general.  It is also desirable
since it is complementary to natural-physical relationships suggesting
that all resources are interrelated and intertwined further indicating
a "general" or biosphere approach to resource management  should
be adopted.

       The proponents of general equilibrium approaches further
suggest that only at the general equilibrium level can the relevant
economic and ecological considerations, decisions and trade-offs
be effectively evaluated in arriving at desirable national (or  even
global) resource management objectives and subsequent policies
designed to achieve these objectives. Water quality induced price
changes (output and input prices), production shifts, process changes,
interindustry interaction and all other second round or secondary
effects of environmental degradation or alternatively,  pollution
abatement standards, must be assessed if definitive results  are
to be realized.  These impacts are  visible only when the problem
is structured in a comprehensive or general equilibrium framework.

       Studies that have utilized general equilibrium methods have
succeeded in quantifying sizeable and in some cases unanticipated
secondary impacts. (3V  For this reason unquestioned reliance on
partial equilibrium studies could result in misdirected and un-
warranted results and priorities.  The  general equilibrium models
must,  therefore, be  preferred to partial equilibrium models if  the
selection  is based solely on theoretical  considerations.

       It  must be  realized, however, that the general models are
in an embryonic stage of development as a water quality manage-
ment tool. Most attempts to develop general models actually involve
adaptation of previously existing general equilibrium models.  Their
success as a practical water quality management tool  (at the present
time and stage of development) is somewhat less than  satisfactory.
They have been applied to small geographical areas with varying
degrees of success but have not been developed,  refined or applied
to assess water quality associated impacts on a national basis.
                             8

-------
       One intrinsic disadvantage of the general models is that
the highly aggregated or general approach obscures a significant
amount of detail.  The amount of detail lost may be sufficient
enough to prevent the approach from becoming a viable water qual-
ity management tool.  (The validity of this  criticism may not be
universally accepted since it is also the general approach and high
level of aggregation that permits and enhances the comparison of
various alternatives and trade-offs  required to maximize net social
welfare.)  There are many natural and physical water quality re-
lated constraints and considerations that are not amenable to high
levels of aggregation.  While it is true that economic considerations
may best be assessed through general equilibrium methods,  the
judicious incorporation of numerous natural and physical consider-
ations ineluctably involved is not achieved through the use of ex-
tensive aggregation or general equilibrium methods.

       The question becomes one of deciding which approach is
feasible in the short run and is also complementary to the solu-
tion of the problem in its long run comprehensive setting.
Unfortunately, data constraints and the present state-of-knowledge
prevents the general models from being considered readily accessible,
viable water quality management tools that can be implemented in
the short run.

       Before leaving the general models, it  should be added that
river basin simulation models appear to possess a considerable
potential for becoming a useful and comprehensive management
tool by approaching the problem within a comprehensive  river
basin framework applied to a specific hydrologic area.  The
adoption of this technique enhances  the possibility of  incorporating
complex water quality and hydrologic characteristics of specific
areas into a meaningful framework thereby further increasing
the likelihood of accurately assessing complex intertwined water
quality associated impacts.  The identification and quantification
of these  interrelated physical characteristics  further facilitates
a definitive assessment of the economic impacts.  Since it is also
possible that pollution abatement standards will, by necessity, be
source oriented, any attempts to quantify effluents by type,  source
and geographic area will also facilitate  the implementation of spatially
dependent  pollution abatement standards.   The river basin simulation
model is one practical way to deal with the comprehensive water qual-
ity problem within a framework that is capable of incorporating com-
plex hydrologic relationships.  It must be realized that at the present
time,  this technique has been applied to only selected basins and sub-
basins with the general application  of this procedure to all major  river
basins remaining relatively unexplored  and incomplete.

-------
       It is also interesting to note that one other general equil-
ibrium approach to water quality management has frequently been
utilized by various research groups.  This method is input-output
analysis.  The complex interindustry impacts of deteriorating water
quality or pollution abatement standards can best be identified and
quantified with the aid of this method of analysis. While the river
basin simulation models are perhaps more sensitive to the hydro-
logic relationships within a region, input-output analysis is best
suited to quantifying complex interindustry relationships.

       A word of caution is  also in order at this  juncture.  The
quest for national water quality associated benefit and cost of
control estimates and functions has prompted some to generalize
previously completed area studies to acquire the desired national
estimates.  It must be realized that spatial differences in econ-
omic activity,  hydrologic conditions, as well as  extreme variations
in prevailing water quality and water quality requirements severely
limits the value and creditability of national estimates or functions
acquired in such a manner.  The methodological and theoretical
assumptions appropriate for small area studies are not  necessarily
appropriate when larger geographical areas are  considered.  Such
attempts are, therefore, acceptable only  if the limitations and dan-
gers are explicitly recognized and if more acceptable methods are
unrealistic due to time and effort constraints.  When faced with a
similar problem, M. M. Kelso reached a most appropriate con-
clusion:

           Man is damned forever to partial incremental choice
           criteria,  in part because  of the limitations of his
           finite mind and in part because the peak criterion
           in his collective  choice must be objectified,  ver-
           balized and quantified, distilling away some  of the
           subjective value  feelings implicit in ultimate goals.

           The economic analyst serving as an expert consultant
           to the public decision maker is doubly damned, not
           only to partial incremental choices, but to working with
           only a few sub-set criteria within the two sub-class
           criteria of economic efficiency and economic equity.
           He  is restricted  to sub-sets so few that he can handle
           their complex interrelations and so sharply delineated
           that he can sense them clearly and quantify them ac-
           curately.

           The practical consideration for us as economic
           analysis is  how partial must we be? ( 4 )

                             10

-------
                 Partial Equilibrium Analysis
        The second type of approach based on the above taxonomy
is partial equilibrium analysis--partial in the respect that no attempt
is made to view the entire problem with all of its ramifications and
implications.  These studies characteristically incorporate various
methodologies and procedures tailored to isolating and studying
certain facets of the water quality problem in detail.  In general,
they tend to be problem-project-crisis oriented in nature in that
they typically are concerned with estimating or quantifying only a
small portion of the primary or first round impacts that are of im-
mediate interest or importance.  Many of these studies are there-
fore differentiating in that they assess various water quality reper-
cussions without regard for how the results or methods contribute
to the solution of other questions or contribute to the total.

        While these models are adequate  for the particular problem
they are addressing, it must be kept in mind that they are partial
in nature and as  such are not designed to assess the total impacts of
water quality deterioration.  There is a temptation to apply these
approaches to the solution of the total problem by aggregating the
results  of various partial studies to achieve national water quality
associated benefit and costs of  control functions.  Since these studies
and methods are designed  to satisfy or answer only isolated micro-
economic aspects of the problem,  such attempts to aggregate are
inevitably subject to methodological criticisms.  For example,  a
variety  of studies have assessed the impacts of water pollution  or
pollution abatement standards as applicable to a particular industry.
These studies frequently assume constant  (input and output) prices,
production patterns and processes. Under these rather restrictive
assumptions, industry impacts  can be accurately assessed.  When,
however, all industries are subject to pollution impacts or abate-
ment standards or water quality deterioration simultaneously, the
derived results are no longer applicable  due to the violation of the
study assumptions,  i.e., the constancy of relative prices, produc-
tion patterns and production processes.  The fallacy of composition
is quickly encountered.  By changing  the scope of the problem
(attempting to sum various partial studies), the problem itself
changes.  The partial studies are by-and-large  essentially non-
additive, and somewhat noncomparable in nature due to variations
in methodologies, procedures and assumptions.
                               11

-------
       It is also  surprising and perhaps shocking to search the
literature and discover the very limited number of partial equili-
brium studies that have attempted to identify and quantify com-
prehensive first  round water quality associated benefits and costs.
In all the literature that was reviewed for Phase I and II,  very few
"comprehensive" partial equilibrium studies materialized.

       One of the many techniques that have been utilized in partial
equilibrium analysis has been the cost benefit analysis.  The following
material included in Phase I as a  summary of the weaknesses of
traditional benefit cost analysis for dealing with environmental
quality issues, is applicable to the evaluation  of any and all partial
equilibrium analysis as an approach to water quality management:
            Traditional benefit cost analysis has numerous
            short falls as a management tool to evaluate
            policies designed to improve environmental
            quality.

            "Most benefit cost approaches are inadequate
            not because there is anything wrong with using
            a benefit cost ratio per se,  but because frequently
            the benefit estimations, a good many of the cost
            estimations, the treatment of uncertainty, and
            all of the time discount rates are improperly
            derived." (Whipple,  1971)

            Two  general limitations of benefit cost analysis
            have been concisely summarized by Prest and
            Turvey (1965).  "First, cost benefit analysis as
            generally understood  is a technique for taking
            decisions within a  framework which has  to be
            decided upon in advance and which involves a
            wide range of considerations, many of them of
            a political or social character.  Secondly, cost
            benefit techniques  as  so far developed, are least
            relevant and serviceable for what one  might call
            large-size investment decisions.  If investment
            decisions are so large relatively to a  given econ-
            omy. ..,  that they  are likely to alter the constel-
            lation of relative outputs and prices over the whole
            economy, the standard technique is likely to fail
            us, for nothing less than some sort of general
            equilibrium approach would suffice in  such cases."
                                12

-------
           The Prest-Turvey critique implies that benefit
           cost analysis can be applied to environmental
           problems only with great difficulty and may be
           conceptually and empirically inappropriate.
           Traditional benefit cost analysis has evolved as
           an analytical device for measuring development
           effects rather than environmental repercussions.
           The result is that a general conceptual framework
           for evaluating pollution abatement policies has not
           been formulated which has  received a generally
           favorable review.  The major difficulty revolves
           around the identification, and measurement of
           benefits from pollution abatement.  Traditional
           benefit measures  used in evaluating development
           projects have limited application to environmental
           repercussions because they have failed to embody
           externalities on affected processes.  It is noted,
           however, that development effects are also a major
           component of social welfare.   Both private and
           public aspects are involved.  ( 5 )

       The evaluation solely  on a theoretical basis has produced two
diametrically opposed results.  The general equilibrium models
view the water quality management problem in a proper conceptual
framework, possess enormous data input requirements and enables
basic trade-offs to be evaluated.  The final output in its aggregated
form especially considering the present state of development has
the disadvantage of lacking  sufficient detail required to be a viable
water quality management tool.

       On the other hand the  partial equilibrium models do not
address  the water quality management problem in a proper con-
ceptual framework. Even the most fundamental trade-offs  occa-
sionally escape the analysis.  They are,  however, more detailed
and amenable to the spatial economic and hydrologic characteristics
embedded in  the water quality management problem than are the
general equilibrium methods.
                               13

-------
       All water quality management models or studies may be
classified as general or partial equilibrium due to the tautologous
nature of the classification scheme adopted.  Unfortunately, how-
ever, the associated merits and resulting recommendations emanating
from such a classification scheme are not as straightforward and
concise as the classification scheme itself.   The search for im-
mediate answers dictates the adoption of an adhoc procedure util-
izing the strengths of both types of models,  i.e., from the partial
equilibrium studies functional estimates of water quality associated
benefits--interpreted as first approximations--may be obtained and
subsequently tempered, conditioned and interpreted with the insight
gained from selected general equilibrium studies.
 Evaluation on an Implementational Basis

        An evaluation on any other basis other than a theoretical
 basis may be subject to some criticism in that either an approach
 is theoretically sound and should be pursued or theoretically de-
 ficient  and should be abandoned.  Statements similar to the above,
 as well as other methodological decision rules, have considerable
 appeal; however, there are a variety of reasons justifying con-
 tinued development of the partial equilibrium models as a means
 of acquiring national water quality associated benefits and cost
 estimates.

        The reasons for this are obvious,   First, the complexity
 and magnitude of the water quality problem with many presently
 unknown and unidentified relationships frequently necessitated the
 adoption of very pragmatic simplified and approximating procedures.
 The level of effort associated with general equilibrium analysis is
 frequently staggering and completely prohibitive. Secondly,  many
 of the functional relationships required in a comprehensive or gen-
 eral equilibrium study  are presently lacking, i.e. , many of the
 first round or primary impacts and  relationships are not under-
 stood or specified and frequently these  relationships  are essential
 inputs in the construction of general equilibrium models.  Thirdly,
many studies must be concerned with the local impacts of water
quality  deteriorations and as  such must adopt partial equilibrium
methods as opposed to  general equilibrium methods due to the inherent
difficulties of adopting  general equilibrium technique to the evaluation
of economic  impacts of small  geographical areas.  Lastly, there are
                               14

-------
many aspects  of the water quality management problem that have to
be approached on a disaggregated level. For example,  desired water
quality depends on beneficial use (withdrawal, nonwithdrawal, con-
sumptive and nonconsumptive use).  Since  water use is spatially de-
pendent and water qualities vary from area to area, the imposition of
a universal water quality standard is not consistent with basic econ-
omic efficiency objectives.  The quintessence of the above items is
that there are  many consj.derations which tend to indicate that water
quality items may have to be  viewed and analyzed with partial
equilibrium techniques as a first approximation to the eventual
solution.

        It, therefore, appears that both types of approaches (general
equilibrium and partial equilibrium) have their own  respective
strengths and limitations which differ  drastically when different
criteria (theoretical as opposed  to implementational) are used in
the evaluation process.
Summary Statement

       Before proceeding to other considerations,  it is perhaps
desirable to summarize in general terms some objective and sub-
jective conclusions that have been formulated as of this point.

       In general, there is evidence of considerable  lack of
direction and coordination in the water quality management
literature.    This limitation has been recognized by  others and
is succinctly summarized by Kneese and Bower (1968).  "In most
regions, water quality management is at a primitive  level.  At the
same time, the technical and analytical means for implementing
such systems are developing rapidly.  The institutional means lag
far behind."  ( 6)

       There is also the failure on the part of many to recognize
the primary source of the environmental quality problem which
inevitably leads to a symptomatic approach to the problem rather
than a direct confrontation of the major factors involved in the
water quality management problem.   More precisely, many partial
equilibrium studies delineate various aspects of the water quality
management issue for detailed analysis without regard for how the
particular  segments can be fitted together to portray the total pic-
ture. Many of the partial equilibrium studies are  highly project-
problem-crisis oriented and contribute very little  to  the derivation
                                15

-------
of national benefit and cost of control functions.  This is further
complicated by the fact that the partial equilibrium studies typically
consider only a very small portion of the total first round or pri-
mary impacts of water quality deterioration.  The cost or risks of
generalizing or aggregating these studies  to derive national benefit
and costs, of control estimates and functions may indeed be  great.
This is particularly true when one considers the extreme variation
in area water qualities, effluent flows, assimilative capacity and
economic activity.

        Neither approach (general or partial) has been adequately
developed  so as to be a  readily available tool applicable to the
problem at hand (derivation of national water quality  associated
benefit cost estimates and functions).  The general equilibrium
approaches currently lack the requisite data input and the partial
equilibrium studies have not corrected this basic deficiency by
providing the  required functional relationships and data input in
general.  This paradoxical and circuitous conclusion is a rather
uncomfortable summary of the  effectiveness  of past endeavors
considering the urgency of various water quality management tasks.
A unified sense  of direction and coordination satisfying both long
run management objectives and short run goals  must be developed.

        An appropriate  summary is provided by Professor Kelso.
"The complexity of multiple sub-set mixes together with the diffi-
culties inherent in analysis of the effects of investment on the  total
economic system  in space and time has led analysts such as Profes-
sor Wantrup and Lindblom to reject any notion that maximization of
a peak criterion is possible and to assert that the best man can do
is to make his partial comparisons among an available array of
alternatives and to choose the one which appears in the light of
present considerations to  generate consequences that move in  the
direction of the preferred state at an acceptable  rate of speed  and
sacrifice."  (7)

       Arthur Maass has likewise concluded, "After the agencies
have learned how  to work with two-term objective functions, they
can try to  solve for more complex ones."  ( 8 )
                               16

-------
D.   Research Needs and Priorities

       The statements above outline the primary environmental
management problem and assess the principal existing water
quality management literature.  With this foundation, attention
is turned toward establishment of research needs and priorities.

       Acceptance of the primary problem is far from satisfying
since it is  realized that its solution would require an unacceptable
long time frame.  Many critical areas  of water pollution cannot be
postponed for this length of time.   In the  interim, partial or
secondary  problems must be addressed.

       To  facilitate further discussion, we have classified the
secondary  problems into two general categories:  (1) data input
needs, and (2) methodological and theoretical research needs.
Subsequently, a summary of priority research needs are presented.
Data Input Needs

       The  solution of problems cannot be fruitfully pursued until
the required data base has been provided. Water quality manage-
ment problems are not unique in this respect.  From the state-of-
the-art review and the preceding evaluation of existing work presented
in this report, it should  be no surprise that cost and benefit data in-
put constraints represents one of the largest obstacles that must be
hurdled in the search of  a satisfactory solution to the environmental
management problem.

       At the  present time the physical,  biological,  chemical and
engineering data input has not been provided in sufficient detail.
Even though the effects of some pollutants have been identified
and quantified, a comprehensive understanding of all natural and
physical relationships associated with water quality is far  from
complete.   These  relationships must be established if the damages
of deteriorating water quality or benefits from mandatory pollution
abatement standards are to be  assessed.  The absence of such data
input at the  present time limits the accuracy of comprehensive national
benefit and cost functions associated with deteriorating water quality
and likewise severely limits the assessment of benefits accruing from
water quality  improvement.
                                17

-------
       Some of the physical,  chemical, biological, economic and
engineering data  input needs include,  but are not limited to, the
following items:

       1.  Relationships between waste treatment cost and effluent
           water quality for  each pollutant and for each type of in-
           dustrial and municipal wastes.

       2.  The quantity of each pollutant from non-point sources
           which enters each receptor.

       3.  The extent of assimilation of each pollutant by natural
           processes in each receptor.

       4.  The effect of each pollutant on municipal and industrial
           water treatment processing costs where surface waters
           are used for municipal and industrial water supplies.

       5.  The effects of untreated pollutants on industrial and
           domestic activities.

       6.  The effect of each pollutant on fish and wildlife support
           capabilities.

       7.   The relationships  between recreational usage and
           water quality, i.e. ,  contact and noncontact water
           based recreational demand and water quality.

       8.  Effects of each pollutant on the useful life of each
           reservoir and lake.

       9.  Effects of each pollutant on health.

      10.  Effects of each  pollutant on final receptors such as
           Lake  Erie,  Gulf of Mexico and oceans.

      11.  Establishment of regional functions relating degree
           of treatment and resulting water quality.
                           18

-------
       Without the knowledge of the above relationships, attempts
to optimize regional or national water quality will be limited to a
"hit and miss" basis without a well defined sense of direction.
The results emanating therefrom will quite likely be highly suspect
in the absence of basic well specified relationships such as those
listed above.

       Although a comprehensive understanding of all of the
physical-natural relationships is  not available at the present time
and will not be in the immediate future.  Efforts to fully utilize
existing data are noticeably absent.  Many problem-project-crisis
oriented studies provide point estimates of benefits and/or costs
of control associated with water quality while the development of
functional relationships relating benefits and costs to specific un-
desirable water quality constituents,  are basically lacking at the
present time and represent a pressing constraint.  This is par-
ticularly true of water quality associated benefit functions.  There
are a variety of reasons other than data  availability that are  respon-
sible for this shortcoming.  The existence of externalities,  in-
tangible and indirect effects,  the lack of an acceptable aggregation
scheme and an acceptable unit of measure valuing nonmonetary
benefits has  increased the difficulties of constructing a  compre-
hensive composite water quality benefit function.  The identification
and quantification of these effects must also be considered an urgently
pressing research problem.

       Even though some consider the development of appropriate
benefit estimation methodology and subsequent establishment of
water quality associated benefit functions as perhaps the single
most pressing water research problem, the establishment of a
composite cost of control function also represents a significant
research deficiency.  While data availability is one constraint
that must be eliminated or at  least partially circumvented,  the
successful completion of these activities--establishment of both
water quality associated benefit and cost functions--also hinges
on the successful fulfillment of certain currently unresolved and
unsupported methodological and theoretical and objective tasks.
                               19

-------
       Without the establishment of the above functional relation-
ships,  the area of concentration  (specific pollutants, receptors
and pollution sources), optimal timing of pollution abatement in-
vestment, optimization of regional and national water quality,
and consequences  of deferred action cannot be ascertained.
While these functional relationships depend on data availability,
certain methodological and theoretical implications are intrinsically
involved  and are of equal importance.
Methodological and Theoretical Research Needs
       A series of general methodological and theoretical research
needs are presented next without regard for data and methodology
constraints.  These needs stem from the primary resource manage-
ment problem as described above.  Water quality management is
required in a dynamic setting and over a  broad range of hydrologic
and economic conditions.  The common property resource aspects
of the problem with the prevalence of externalities complicates
the issues  involved.  These and other factors are embedded in the
general research needs below.

       Some general methodological and  theoretical research
problems and needs (not listed in order of priority) include:

       1.   Development of methods and procedures to identify
           and quantify water associated benefit and cost func-
           tions relating specific benefits and costs to specific
           pollutants.

       2.   Development of economic and hydrologic models to
           identify and quantify complex intra- and  interbasin
           relationships.

       3.   Extension and refinement of accounting measures,
           such as "insurance values," for uncertain water
           quality associated costs and benefits.

       4.   Formulation of a measure of value that can be used as
           a common denominator additive measure to effectively
           evaluate all intangible and indirect nonmonetary costs
           and benefits associated with changes in water quality.
                               20

-------
    (Since many of the potential benefits of water quality
    protection or improvement are intangible and indirect
    esthetic,  health and ecological benefit that are not
    measured by market transactions,  an accurate esti-
    mate of composite benefits is not generally possible
    within present day methodologies.)

5.  Development of alternative pollution abatement policies
    designed  to minimize undesirable equity and distribu-
    tion impacts associated with water  quality control.

6.  Quantification of complex water quality substitution
    effects.  As water quality deteriorates, certain sub-
    stitution effects may be expected.   Water using acti-
    vities and processes will begin seeking alternative
    input sources, processes and outlets as water quality
    deteriorates.  For example, water quality degradation
    will directly and indirectly encourage reduced expendi-
    tures on water based  recreational activity.   The reduc-
    tion in water based expenditures represents a loss to
    this sector of the economy.   If one  is  interested  in
    national impacts of water quality deterioration, the
    correct figure is not the total reduction in only water
    based recreational expenditures but rather  the net
    reduction or impacts  associated with the change  in
    total recreational expenditures, i.e., explicitly recog-
    nizing the substitution phenomenon.  These complex
    relationships must be further developed if realistic
    national benefit and cost of control  functions are to be
    established.  (9)
7.   Development of an aggregation framework to assess
     regional and national pollution control costs and benefits.

8.   Assessment of alternative political,  legal and institu-
     tional arrangements needed to perform water pollution
     control management functions.
                       21

-------
        9.   Development of procedures to project and evaluate
            alternative distributions of benefits and costs
            through time, i.e. ,  "time profiles," including the
            use of a social discount rate to compute present
            value.

       10.   Estimation of net social benefits attributable to water
            pollution control measures,  i.e.,  measurement of a
            social welfare function.  "Water pollution  control
            measures are expected to impact economic structures
            with consequent relative shifts in supply and demand
            relationships.  Such consequences call for analysis of
            the social welfare function.

        The above list includes a variety of methodological and
 theoretical research needs,  some of which suggest that a sub-
 stantial reassessment of commonly held social objectives is in
 order.  The listing is presented in broad terms and unstructured
 in reference to the assignment of priorities.  No attempt has  been
 made at this time to indicate  th priorities associated  with these
 research needs or to classify them into short run or  long run  needs,
 What,  therefore,  remains to  be accomplished is the establishment
 of research needs and priorities with data and methodology con-
 straints.
Long Run Economic Research Needs and Priorities
       The objective of this section is to provide a general summary
of "ordered" research needs.  (To the extent possible,  the order
reflects priorities for these research needs.) Many of these re-
search needs and priorities are well documented while others are
the product of Phase I and the subsequent evaluation.  Long run
and short run research needs and priorities are presented in
summary and enumerated form below.
                              22

-------
The long run economic research needs include:

1.  Develop a comprehensive common property resource
    allocation system to assist in the efficient allo-
    cation and utilization of common property resources--
    endogenous  or exogenous  of the market mechanism.
    Alternative  institutional structures are implicitly
    involved.

2.  Further develop and implement general equilibrium
    models specifically designed to assess the  economic
    impacts of changing water quality and mandatory pollu-
    tion abatement standards.

3.  Refine the above  mentioned models until they possess
    the required degree of  sophistication to evaluate qom-
    plex trade-offs at the aggregate level but still possess
    the detail required to be useful regional water quality
    management tools. Incorporate measures  to achieve
    dynamic efficiency realizing that production process,
    technology,  demographic  and social preference changes
    occur.

4.  Develop a measure of value that can be used as a common
    denominator, additive measure of intangible or indirect
    water quality associated benefits and costs.

5.  Develop "insurance values" or alternative measures
    designed to  handle unknown contingencies associated
    with water quality determination.

6.  Reassess and evaluate  the social discount jrate currently
    used  in evaluating public  investment projects.

7.  Explore regional, national and international legal,
    institution and structural changes required for effective
    monitoring and surveillance of emissions and  realization
    of environmental objectives.
                          23

-------
       The above hierarchy of long term economic research needs
is somewhat misleading in that it is extremely difficult to assign
meaningful priorities in that all are requisite to an effective and
lasting solution to the environmental management problem.  In the
interim it is  expedient to concentrate on less ambitious short run
research needs and priorities.
Short Run Economic Research Needs and Priorities

        The following items constitute economic research needs
that could be at least partially satisfied in the short run given
existing data and methodology constraints.  The three major
divisions and  subdivisions are listed in their relative order  of
importance.

        It should not be surprising to find that benefit estimation is
the singularly most important need to be satisfied in the short run.

        I.   Develop, refine and  implement methodology for
            assessing water quality associated impacts with
            special emphasis on the following short run re-
            search needs.

            A.  Benefit estimation
                1.  Refinement of overall benefit estimation
                    methodology.
                2.  Refinement and implementation of intangible
                    benefit estimation methodology and techniques.
                3.  Estimation  of substitution impacts.
                4.  Development of multivariate water quality
                    associated benefit functions.
                5.  Interfacing  economic, hydrologic, biological
                    and engineering water quality models.
                6.  Estimation  of irreversible damages.
                7.  Development of a satisfactory aggregation
                    scheme.
                                  24

-------
      B.  Cost estimation
          1.  Refinement of overall cost of pollution abate-
              ment methodology.
          2.  Development of nonpoint pollution estimate and
              cost of treatment.
          3.  Development of a treatment versus resulting
              stream quality function.
          4.  Further development of least cost treatment
              strategies.
          5.  Development of cost aggregation framework.

      C.  Implicit in all of the above items is the development
          of a satisfactory data  base including but not limited
          to the following items,
          1.  Pollutant level by receptor
          2.  Effluent flows by source
          3.  Effluent flows by process
          4.  Precise water quality monitoring data
          5.  Damage thresholds and  impact ranges
          6.  Critical effluent levels
          7.  Synergistic effects

 II.   Develop pollution abatement policy alternatives with
      special emphasis on the following items:

      A.  Development of spatially variable policies and
          abatement standards.
      B.  Minimization of adverse equity and distribution
          effects.
      C.  Development of alternative policies  to provide in-
          ternal incentives  to reduce effluent loads.

III.   Analysis and inauguration of institutional and  structural
      changes required to implement many of the above items.
                            25

-------
 Immediate Research Needs and Priorities

        While all of the above items constitute short run economic
 research needs and priorities that could be eliminated given pre-
 sent data and methodology constraints, there is great disparity in
 the importance or urgency associated with each of these items.
 There is also the need to further develop and refine techniques
 useful in appraising short run priorities so as to insure that
 current resources and efforts are properly directed.  For this
 reason those items representing the greatest need have been
 singled out and listed below:

        1.  Continue to develop,  refine and implement procedures
            useful in ascertaining the most detrimental pollutants.
        2.  Continued refinement of water quality associated benefit
            estimation methodology.
        3.  Development and implementation of benefit estimation
            methodology appropriate for the estimation of intangible
            water quality associated benefits.
        4.  Investigation of complex water quality  substitution
            effects.
        5.  Development and implementation of multivariant
            benefit function (relating benefits to several key
            pollutants).
        6.  Interfacing economic, biological, hydrological and
            engineering models.
E.   Subjective and Objective Benefit and Cost Estimates

       In addition to the above  research needs and priorities there
is considerable value to be gained in further summarizing and
assessing the current status of benefit and cost estimates.  For
the most part these  items are rather subjective and tenuous but
possess considerable value in that the urgency of present action
requires prompt and immediate deployment of pollution abatement
measures in selected areas  representing the greatest immediate
and short run need.   It is with this thought that a variety of sub-
jective and objective water quality associated benefit and cost
matrices have been  developed and presented in Appendix A  of
this report.  It should be recognized that this represents only a
first approximation  of what is presented as the number one im-
mediate research need.
                               26

-------
F.   Directions of Further Study

       The above material  represents an extension beyond the state-
of-the-arts review by providing a critical evaluation of the existing
literature based on several delineating criteria.  While this extension
was  not explicitly required,  it must be either explicitly or implicitly
considered in the development of the research needs and priorities.
The  specification of areas of needed emphasis further requires
selection be made on the basis of current research development.
The  state-of-the-arts and the numerous complexities encountered
seem to  indicate that the water quality management task is an incessant
project that requires further elaboration and extension at every inter-
vening step.

       This is indeed the justification for much of the remainder of
this  report.  Detailed analysis of existing work has revealed many
methodological shortcomings that should be addressed.  The material
that  follows makes inroads  toward the eventual solution of several cur-
rent water quality associated methodological and theoretical problems.

       In the  subsequent chapters, the only type of approach that is
considered is partial equilibrium analysis.  Considering the current
state-of-the-arts and level  of effort considerations, this is the only
feasible  approach.   Several partial equilibrium  studies are reviewed
in detail followed by various extensions. Alternative approaches
possessing considerable merit are also developed.

       Chapter II deals with general methodology in a partial equili-
brium framework.   Several partial equilibrium  studies are appraised
and alternative approaches  and procedures are also explored.  Most of
the remainder of the report (Chapters,  III, IV and V) is  concerned with
further elaboration of these  techniques.

       Chapter VI is a  general summary of this phase of the project
and proposed  areas of emphasis  for future research.
                                 27

-------
                          Footnotes
(1)  Milliman, J. W. ,"Welfare Economics, and Resource Develop-
    ment," in Ian Burton and Robert W.  Kates (eds.)» Readings In
    Resource Management and Conservation,  the University of
    Chicago Press,  1965.

(2)  Mangum,  F. A., Jr.,  Policy Alternatives for Environmental
    Improvement, Department of Economics, North Carolina State
    University,  1972.  (Unpublished Report)

(3)  Kite, J.  C.  and Eugene A. Laurent, "An  Economic-Ecologic
    Model for Evaluating the Environmental Repercussion of Area
    Development, " American Journal of Agricultural Economics,
    Dec. ,  1971.

(4)  Kelso, M. M. ,  "The Criterion Problem in Decision-Making
    for Public Investment," Water Resources and Economic
    Development of the West.  Report No. 15, Economic Criteria
    Water Transfer, Economics of Water Quality,  Economics of
    Ground Water.  Conference Proceedings, Committee on the
    Economics  of Water Resource Development of the Western
    Agricultural Economics Research Council, Dec. 1966.

(5)  Unger,  S. G. , M. J. Emerson and D. L. Jordening,  State-
    of-the-Art Review: Pollution Control Benefits and Costs with
    Emphasis on Water, A report to the Environmental Protection
    Agency, Economic Analysis Branch, Washington, D. C.,  1973.

(6)  Kneese, A. V. and Blair T. Bower,  Managing Water Quality;
    Economics,  Technology,  Institutions, Resources for the Future,
    Inc., John Hopkins Press,  1968.

(7)  Ibid, i  Kelso, M. M.

(8)  Maass, A., Benefit Cost Analysis:"Its Relevance to Public
    Investment Decisions, " The Quarterly Journal of Economics,
    May 1966.
                               28

-------
(9)  In general,  the substitution phenomenon referred to frequently
    in this report stems from the fact that there are alternative
    uses of capital in the economy and also that there are numerous
    alternative consumer expenditure outlets.  This opportunity con-
    cept is frequently encountered but seldom recognized in studies
    assessing the economic impact of water quality degradation
    (primarily because most  studies are problem-project-crisis
    oriented and are interested in ascertaining the economic im-
    pacts of water quality degradation in reference to only one
    isolated sector of the economy).

    Kneese and Bower have,  however, explicitly recognized this
    phenomenon in a discussion of a hypothetical example concerning
    markets, externalities and the  social costs  of pollution.  The
    example assumes that pollution results in the destruction of a
    downstream fishing industry that utilizes resources valued at
    100 and producing an annual return of  10. Upstream pollution
    results in the distinction  of the industry and the conclusion
    reached is that ". . .the social cost of killing fish is 10 not 110
    (market value of the fish), as is often implied in exhortations
    to assess waste discharges with the cost of  damages they cause."
    (Reference 6)

    The  results, however, are predicted on the assumption that
    the resources can be transferred to other sectors of the econ-
    omy at no cost to other productive uses at either the same  or
    different locations.

    This general concept, however, is particularly relevant
    and must not be overlooked when the goal is to assess national
    net social benefits of water pollution abatement or  water quality
    associated benefit and cost functions.  It is  also hypothesized
    that  this phenomenon is particularly important in water quality
    associated recreational activities in that there are  a variety of
    outdoor recreational activities  that are close  substitutes for
    water based recreational activity. The increasing  mobility
    of the population in general would  seem to indicate  greater
    flexibility in the  selection of type and location of possible
    recreational substitutes.

    The  summary of this brief digression is  that as water quality
    deteriorates, increased expenditures on skiing, camping,
    sightseeing,  travel, tennis may be expected.  The net social
    cost  of water quality degradation must reflect this phenomenon.

-------
                        SEC TTON II

       A GENERAL METHODOLOGICAL APPROACH


A.   Optimization of Net jiocialJVelfare

       The underlying objective of the relatively recent environ-
mental quality thrust is not a new phenomenon but rather the inter-
minable pursuit of the maximization of human welfare.  In this
respect the basic social objective has  remained unaltered.  The
uninterrupted growth of national income  and the unprecedented
expansion of material wealth has permitted a reassessment  of
priorities resulting in a shift from material welfare objectives
to intangible quality of life considerations.  The basic objectives
and tasks of the economist throughout  the transitory period have,
however, remained the  same--developing criteria, analytical tools,
decision rules and guidelines to aid and facilitate policy makers in
their endeavors to develop policies and a general atmosphere con-
ducive to the attainment of social welfare objectives.

       The shift in emphasis has been accompanied by a host of
complications  and complexities that are rather tenuous in nature
and difficult to assimilate into existing analytical techniques.  A
major portion of the complications arising from the shift in  empha-
sis can be attributed to the need for establishing values  and  meas-
ures  appropriate for and associated with numerous direct, indirect
and intangible social welfare components.   While there has always
existed a need to consider,  identify and quantify intangible social
welfare components, the increased emphasis on non-material
welfare has  greatly increased this need.  While the challenges are
great and the obstacles  are many, they must be overcome or cir-
cumvented one by one if a lasting and equitable water quality
management solution is to be achieved.

       It is difficult to think of another resource that has more
social welfare implications than does water.  Water is used in
virtually every production process,  it is an essential human and
natural life support ingredient and further has certain intrinsic
esthetically pleasing qualities in its  unpolluted state.  The degra-
dation of water quality impairs its value in all uses in varying
degrees.  It is therefore difficult to  conceptualize or formulate
the water quality management problem in any other framework
other than a  social welfare maximization problem.
                             30

-------
       The salient point of the above at first glance may appear
to be directing the discussion back to the general equilibrium as
opposed to partial equilibrium controversy that has been encoun-
tered in Phase I and the preceding evaluation.  This, however,
is not the case as  the only method of analysis to be encountered
for  the duration of the report is partial equilibrium analysis.  The
essence of the above is, however,  that even though partial equili-
brium analysis will be utilized (as  the only practical approach at
the  present time), the acceptance or rejection of the welfare maxi-
mizing objective or goal has significant methodological implications.
That is,  the adoption of partial equilibrium techniques is an explicit
recognition that many of the impacts of water quality degradation
will escape quantification.  This does not,  however,  require the
relinquishment of ones obligations  to recognize and consider various
welfare implications that are normally disregarded in partial equil-
ibrium techniques.

       The vociferation by the general public for environmental
standards,  the subsequent establishment of the Environmental
Protection Agency and the ensuing pollution abatement standards
is certain manifestation that the general public desires and values
environmental protection.  It would, however, be foolhardy to assume
that material welfare is no longer valued or a relevant welfare con-
sideration.  The final decision in reference to the desirability of
pollution abatement standards must be based on total social welfare
which is comprised of material wellbeing and other intangible con-
siderations such as esthetic appreciation emanating from environ-
mental quality enhancement.  Any  technique or method of analysis
used to assess environmental degradation must therefore incorpor-
ate or consider as many facets of water quality impairment as pos-
sible or at least explicitly recognize those considerations that are
relevant but not included because of data or state  of knowledge con-
straints.   Procedures that attempt to portray the  total benefits of
water quality enhancement without explicit recognition of the many
limiting factors are truly derelict  in their  duty and oblivious of
their true  obligations.  Any partial equilibrium techniques  adopted
must therefore constantly guard against becoming overly structured
or limited thereby omitting numerous essential considerations.
Several of the above precautions will be recalled as needed at vari-
ous points in later discussions.
                               31

-------
       In addition to the above mentioned welfare considerations,
there are a variety of other pertinent considerations that must be
recognized preliminary to the discussion of specific estimation
techniques that can be used to derive national water quality associ-
ated benefit and cost estimates.   Some of these items are listed
below.

       1.   The value of water is derived from its use (withdrawal,
            nonwithdrawal, consumptive and nonconsumptive--
            including intangible uses such as esthetic appreciation).
            The assessment of the impacts of water quality degrada-
            tion must therefore proceed on an individual beneficial
            use basis since the individual uses are differentially
            impacted by water quality deterioration.

       2.   Since dissimilar pollutants  in varying concentrations
            are more critical to some beneficial uses than to
            others,  a specific pollutant by beneficial use assess -
            ment of water quality deterioration must be adopted.

       3.   The concentration of specific pollutants is equally im-
            portant.  If present in low concentrations, some pollu-
            tants have minimal damage  potential while at higher  con-
            centrations their presence may significantly impair the
            utilitarian value of water.   Other pollutants may be
            damaging at high and  low concentrations with minimal
            damage at intermediate levels,  e.g., florides.   The
            assessment of damage potentials must therefore be
            with respect to a range of watejr quality levels if a
            meaningful assessment of net benefits is  to be realized.

       4.   Since economic activity is not dispersed uniformly over
            the landscape and hydrologic conditions are also spatiallv
            variable, it follows from the above three  items  that varvi
            spatially dependent water quality _standards  should be~evalV
           uated to assure economic efficiency and maximization of
            social welfare objectives.  It also directly follows that
           benefit and cost estimates applicable  to one geographical
           area may not be applicable to other areas.

       5.   By a complete assessment of both natural and man-made
           pollutants and area economic and hydrologic conditions,
           a social welfare area  optimizing water quality could be
           c onceptualized.
                             32

-------
       6.   The maximization of water associated net social bene-
            fits dictates that optimal timing of pollution control
            expenditures, total impacts^ (primary and secondary),
            point of treatment and complex substitution effects
            be  further examined  in detail.

       7.   Combination of the above points suggests a potential
            danger in adopting universal industry and interin-
            dustry abatement standards irrespective of local
            economic and hydrologic conditions.


       In the quest for a social welfare maximizing water quality
solution, the first step may be in the direction of estimating bene-
fit and cost of control functions.  As suggested above, a number of
important water quality variables exist.  Suspended solids, dis-
solved oxygen, biochemical oxygen demand, coliform count, in-
organic phosphate, nitrogen,  pH, water hardness  and dissolved
solids are some of the more important variables.   In searching
for the optimum water quality in a particular receptor, each of
these variables has certain costs and benefits associated with it.
National estimates of net benefits must be with respect to a certain
quality of water.  Furthermore,  it is well known that the optimum
quality of water varies both because  of natural terrain and human
activity patterns.  At Lake Tahoe the optimum quality is  different
from that in the lower portion of the  Missouri river, for example.
Because of this a procedure  is needed which can lead to both an
understanding of optimum quality in a specific basin as well as
national estimates of net benefits.

       The significance of the above is that water quality manage-
ment, if couched in a  social -welfare  setting, is  not a single variate
problem that can be easily portrayed in simple pedestrian terms.
Water quality management is a multidimensional problem that must
be formulated in a manner that is appropriate and consistent with
multidimensionality.  It is further possible that the unique spatial
characteristics of water quality management and the multidimen-
sionality in general may, in the end, be of such overwhelming im-
portance that water quality management on a basis other than a
small region by region approach may be self-defeating and totally
void of meaning.
                             33

-------
        In view of the multiplicity of factors that must be considered,
 it is indeed not surprising that few have attempted to establish national
 water quality associated benefit and cost of control functions.  The
 absence of such endeavors has left sizeable voids in the development
 of applicable methodology and estimation techniques.
B.   Objectives

        The fact that the development of national water quality
associated benefit and cost functions is virtually an unexplored
endeavor without precedence or frame of reference, the best
approach may well be to seek out and review procedures and
studies that have undertaken similar objectives on a regional
scale.  A thorough evaluation of such studies can be expected
to provide considerable insight into the strength and limitations
of such techniques.  With this background, it may then be possible
to adopt and extend these techniques and procedures to aid in the
acquisition of national water quality associated benefit and cost
functions or estimates.  Another realistic alternative or possi-
bility is that the limitations of such methods may be found to be
of sufficient amplitude to discourage adaptation efforts in favor
of developing alternative methods and procedures.

        The objectives of the current chapter are to critically
review and evaluate selected techniques,  explore  their potential
as a national water quality assessment tool and to consciously
seek out alternative procedures that are perhaps more amenable
to the task at  hand.
C.   Related Studies

       As has been previously mentioned,  there is almost a total
absence of studies  that have attempted to establish water quality
associated estimates by beneficial use on a national basis.  This
is not to say that national estimates do not exist for they do.  By
and large these  estimates are the result of extrapolating the esti-
mate of selected area studies.  The merits and validity of these
estimates can best be assessed by first evaluating the methodol-
ogies and techniques  utilized to produce the regional estimates
and secondly investigating the limitations and complications
                             34

-------
encountered in extrapolating these regional estimates to derive
national estimates.  The studies that are of primary interest are
those that have undertaken the estimation of comprehensive bene-
fits emanating from water quality improvement in specific basin,
sub-basin, estuary or river reach considering a variety of bene-
ficial uses and specific pollutants.  This limits the selection to a
very limited group of studies.  Some of these  include studies of
water quality impacts associated with the following surface water
bodies:

       1.   Ohio River Basin
    :   2.   Maumee River Basin
       3.   Delaware Estuary
       4.   Potomac Estuary
       5.   Yaquina Bay
       6.   Onondaga Lake

       It must be pointed out at this juncture that these studies can
not be considered to be representative of most areas of the country.
The above geographical areas,  with the exception of portions of the
Maumee  Basin, are either heavy industrial areas,  large population
centers or possess unique recreational features (Yaquina Bay) that
are not typical of  all areas of the country.  The  generalization of
the results from these  studies may therefore be somewhat question-
able.

       Even within this limited group there is a  great variation
in techniques, resulting estimates and the number of beneficial
uses  considered.  Some of the above mentioned  studies would be
classified as general equilibrium studies and  the remainder partial
equilibrium.  It is perhaps most instructive to concentrate on the
partial equilibrium studies and especially those that are closely
akin to possible techniques that may be adopted  and utilized to ac-
quire national water quality associated benefit and cost estimates.
Two of the above  studies--the Ohio and Maumee  River--have there-
fore been selected for  further consideration.

       A pioneering effort to establish regional pollution abate-
ment benefit and cost of control functions is found  in H. C. Bramer's
doctoral dissertation,  I960,  ( 1 ).   The study is a comprehensive
study of the benefits and cost of pollution abatement in the Ohio
River Basin considering several treatment strategies and a large
number of beneficial uses.  The study represents a paramount
contribution to  the state-of-the-knowledge  in  that it was completed
                             35

-------
in I960 and is still considered to be one of the better works which
undertakes the establishment of basin wide water quality associ-
ated benefits and costs.  The analytical technique adopted in this
study is the traditional benefit cost analysis.  Both benefits and
costs of pollution abatement are constructed as  a function of per-
centage reduction in pollution load.

        The pollution abatement benefit function  was constructed
by considering the damages and production expenses that could
be avoided by numerous water-users if the pollution load were
decreased.  In addition other benefits  such as demand shifts re-
sulting from effluent removal were also considered, i.e. , increased
recreational expenditures as a  result of effluent removal. In gen-
eral, very little was done to include other potential benefit con-
cepts such as latent or option demand.  A complete list of the
benefits considered and the dollar estimates associated with
water quality improvement resulting from the inaugurative pri-
mary and secondary treatment  of all emissions  is presented in
 Exhibit II-1.

        The costs of pollution abatement in Bramer's work were,
aa previously stated,  formulated as a  function of percentage re-
duction of pollution load, considering several treatment strategies.
Exhibit II-2 from Bramer presents the above relationships based
on the benefit and cost estimates derived  in the  study.  Primary
and secondary pollution abatement measures represent 40 and 85
percent reduction in effluent loads respectively. The figure is
illustrative of the basic relationships and demonstrates  the func-
tional relationship between costs,  benefits and degree of pollution
abatement.

        It is interesting to note that the costs of  pollution abatement
are greater than benefits derived at all points.  The estimated
annual benefits associated with primary and  secondary abatement
measures were 76.0 and 86.5 percent  of the costs  respectively.
This is even more  significant when it is realized that one benefit--
recreation benefits emanating from effluent removal--accounted
for approximately 78 and 74 percent of the possible cost reductions
effected by primary and secondary treatment level respectively.
This takes on even greater significance when it  is realized that
complex substitution effects were not taken into account, i. e.,
the recreational benefit figure derived is based  solely on the
                             36

-------
Exhibit II-1.  Benefits of pollution abatement measures in the Ohio
       River Valley in the various uses of the surface waters

                                     Reductions in Costs  in 1958 $
       Water Use                  Primary                  Secondary
Municipal Water Supplies
Domestic Use
Industrial Use
Thermal-electric Power
Navigation
Recreation
Hydroelectric Power
Commercial Fishing
Esthetic Enjoyment
$ 2,657,000
6,456,000
5,174,000
1,941,000
2,300,000
80,000,000
30,000
80,000
4,300,000
$ 5,315,000
IE, 912, 000
10,347,000
3,882,000
4,600,000
120,000,000
30,000
121,000
4,300,000
   Totals                         $102,938,000           $161,507,000
   Source:  H. C. Bramer, The Economic Aspects of the Water Pollu-
            tion Abatement Program in the Ohio River Valley, p. 134.
                                37

-------
                      Coats leso
                      Imputtid
                      Tntcruut
                                          Dcnefltt) Lean lVjcn.-atlorwl usoo
                    60            00
Induction of Pollution Load (per cent)
                                                                              100
  Exhibit U.-2*  Annual Costs and Benefits  of Water Pollution Abate-
                 ment Measures.

Source: H. C. Bramer,  The Economic Aspects  of the Water Pollution
         Abatement Program in the Ohio  River Valley,  p. 145.
                                  38

-------
increase in water based recreational activity without considering
possible interaction between other nonwater based recreational
expenditures.  It must also be pointed out that the recreational
benefits are also the most difficult to estimate  due to data availa-
bility and other intangible considerations that are encountered.

       A  slight digression is perhaps in order  at this time in that
the substitution concept will reoccur at various points in later
discussions.  As was stated at the beginning of this chapter, the
objective  of environmental protection policies is  to facilitate the
maximization of net social welfare.  The adoption of this objective
dictates that the substitution phenomenon enter the analysis.  The
true impact of water quality degradation on recreation is not simply
the total change in water based recreational expenditure in that
there are many close substitutes to water based  recreational activity.
that also produce  or yield satisfaction.  As water quality deteriorates
people shift out of water based recreational activities and into other
recreational activities.  It is the net change in recreational expen-
ditures that must be considered.   The substitution phenomenon exist
for all water quality associated impacts but is considered to be most
important when considering recreation  benefits.

The precise  results obtained if substitution effects were considered
is unknown, however, the direction of change is  certain.  The in-
clusion of the substitution effect will lower--and it is further hypothe-
sized that it will substantially lower--the above mentioned benefit
estimates.  As a  result,  the benefit cost ratio  may well be sub-
stantially less than  was estimated by Bramer.

       An extension of Bramer's study can be found in a master's
thesis by J. Matson (  2 ).  The same basic technique was applied
to the Maumee River.  Estimates  of annual benefits and costs of pollution
abatement in this sub-basin produced a benefit cost  ratio of 0. 96 at
approximately 93 percent removal of dissolved organic matter.  Exhibit
II-3 presents the benefit and cost functions estimated by Matson.

       It is expedient to make several  observations and raise
several other questions at this juncture.
                              39

-------
  0]
  lH
  n)
  t-H
  • — I
  o
  Q

  "8

  en
  d
  O
o  w
u  CQ
  g
           80
           70
60
50
           40
           30
           20
           10-
            0
                                                                    O
                                  Annual Costs
          V     V    Annual Benefits
              80
              84
88
92
100
                               BOD  REMOVAL (Percent)
     Exhibit II-3.  Effect of degree of removal of dissolved organic

                   matter from effluents on annual costs and economic

                   benefits due to pollution abatement in the Maumee

                   River Basin.

     Source:  Matson, Jack V., Cost of Industrial and Municipal Water

              Pollution Abatement in the Maumee River Basin, Thesis

              University of Toledo, January,  1968, p. 44.

                                 40

-------
1.   Both studies have established the benefits and costs of
    pollution abatement based on numerous beneficial uses
    relating both benefits and costs to percentage reduction
    in municipal and industrial point source effluent dis-
    charges.  Surface water quality resulting from pollu-
    tion abatement standards depends not only on point
    source  effluents  discharge but also on assimilative
    capacity,  area influent loads and  natural and man-made
    non-point pollutants, i.e. , a 50 percent reduction in
    effluent discharges does not result in a 50 percent
    reduction in surface water effluent loads.  In other
    words the benefit and cost curves derived are applicable
    to only  one point on the water quality spectrum given that
    all of the above factors are constant.  If,  however,  any of
    the above factors change,  an entirely different net benefit
    configuration would result if beneficial use is indeed im-
    pacted by quality of water utilized.

2.   The failure to consider substitution effects reduces
    the credibility of resulting estimates if the objective
    is to ascertain the true social net benefits of pollu-
    tion abatement.

3.   How accurate are the data and how much  reliance can
    be placed in water pollution abatement benefit cost
    ratios or functions when one single benefit component,
    i.e. , recreational expenditures,  comprises  such a
    large percentage of the total benefits.  This  is especially
    true when the benefit is as elusive to measure as is water
    quality associated recreational benefits.  It is not our pur-
    pose here to question the approach or the results but to
    merely point out that those wishing to cast doubt or dis-
    credit the  results of studies similar to the above could
    perhaps do so with little  effort.  The wisdom of attempting
    to justify expenditures  on such a  vital and essential area
    as water pollution abatement control must therefore be
    grounded on a much more solid foundation.

4.  The generalization of these studies to acquire national
    water quality associated benefit and cost  functions may
    be  questioned for a variety of reasons.  First, the Ohio
    river basin is  not representative of many of the nations
    surface water  bodies; second,  the estimation technique
                      41

-------
            used to assess several of the benefits must be con-
            sidered rough approximation only; third, a more com-
            plete assessment of non-point pollution sources and
            loads must be completed; fourth, the conversion from
            percent of treatment to resulting surface water  quality
            must be refined; and fifth, a more complete assessment
            of prevailing treatment strategies and  the incremental
            benefits and costs associated with imposition of addi-
            tional treatment must be considered.
       In all fairness to the above authors, it must be emphasized
that their intent was to show that a substantial portion of the cost
of pollution abatement is  not lost but is returned to society through
the benefits accrued as water quality improves.  This has been ac-
complished in the above studies  by relating benefits and costs to
percent of effluent removal.  It must be recognized,  however, that
the estimation of total net social benefits emanating from water
pollution abatement is quite another matter.

       It does  appear that there may well be sufficient reason
for opposing the extension of the above studies to acquire national
water quality associated benefit  and cost estimates and functions
without further refinement.  The above studies were tailored ex-
plicitly for a specified  geographical area thereby permitting many
simplifications that can not be ignored if the goal is to acquire
national water  quality estimates.
D.  Required Extensions

       One alternative in the search for national water quality
associated benefit and cost estimates and functions is to utilize
the same basic technique incorporated in Bramer's  study but to
extend and supplement the procedures to eliminate some of the
basic limitations.  One approach is to establish water quality
associated benefits and costs as a function of water  quality as
opposed  to percentage reduction in effluent loads.  This is de-
sirable in that the critical objective,  a target variable, is water
                             42

-------
 quality as opposed to reduction in effluent discharges which is
 meaningless without further knowledge of prevailing area water
 quality, relative importance of natural non-point pollutants and
 the resulting surface water quality.  The following material will
 briefly discuss some of the major considerations that are  required
 to estimate water quality associated benefits and costs as  a function
 of water quality.  The major considerations and procedures are
 discussed below with the details  reserved for later chapters.

 Costs of Pollution Abatement

        The selection of appropriate pollution abatement measures
 must proceed on an individual treatment strategy basis.  One type
 of treatment  strategy may successfully eliminate or substantially
 reduce the concentration of one pollutant while  it is totally ineffec-
 tive in the removal of other pollutants.  The cost of pollution  abate-
 ment must therefore proceed on  a strategy by strategy basis.  For
 example, the use of computerized techniques have enabled the costing
 of 35 treatment strategies presented in Exhibit II-4.  The cost of
 pollution abatement as a function of percent treatment (treatment
 strategy) is presented in Exhibit II-5,  including only a representative
 sample of treatment strategies.


        The eleven treatment strategies listed below are frequently
used industrial water treatment processes.  The costs of these
strategies has been estimated by  the Environmental Protection
Agency in The Economics of Clean Water.  (  3 )

        1.  Oil separation
       2.  Equalization
       3.  Coagulation
       4.  Neutralization
       5.  Flotation
       6.  Sedimentation
       7.  Aeration
       8.  Biological stabilization
       9.  Chlorination
      10.  Evaporation
      11.  Incineration
                                43

-------
Exhibit II-4.  Treatment processes that can be costed by the waste-
         water treatment plant cost estimating program

  Raw Sewage Pumping
  Preliminary Treatment (Grit Removal,  Flow Measurement)
  Preliminary Treatment (Grit Removal,  Flow Measurement, Screening)
  Primary Sedimentation (Single Basin)
  Primary Sedimentation (Multiple Basin)
  Primary Sludge Pumping
  Aeration Basin Structure
  Aeration Diffused Air
  Mechanical Aeration Equipment
  Flocsillator
  Trickling Filter
  Intermediate Pumping
  Final or Intermediate Sedimentation (Single Basin)
  Final or Intermediate Sedimentation (Multiple Basin)
  Recirculation Pumping
  Stabilization Ponds
  Sludge Thickener
  Anaerobic Digestion and Building
  Aerobic Digestion
  S3.udge Holding Tanks
  Vacuum Filtratioif (Landfill Disposal of Sludge)
  Vacuum Filtration (Incineration Disposal of Sludge)
  Centrifugation
  Sludge Drying Beds
  Sludge Lagoons
  Multiple Hearth Incineration
  Fluidized Bed Incineration
  Chlorination Building and Equipment
  Chlorination Contact Basin
  Administrative and Laboratory
  Garage and Shop
  Yardwork
  Laboratory - Activated Sludge
  Laboratory - Trickling Filter
  Laboratory - Primary Plant

  Source:  R.  G.  Eilers and Robert Smith, "Wastewater Treatment
          Plant Cost Estimating Program, " Environmental Pro-
           tection Agency, Water Quality Office, Advanced Waste
           Treatment Research Laboratory, Cincinnati, Ohio, April,
           1971.
                              44

-------
       Exhibit II-5.  Cost of treatment and degree of control
                    (by treatment strategy).
st of
.lution
itement
                  12        34        56      Degree of Control
                                                             (By treatment strategy)

          Case 1.   Primary treatment only
          Case 2.   Primary treatment plus secondary (biological) treatment.
          Case 3.   Primary treatment, secondary treatment, plus chlorination
                    of effluent.
          Case 4.   Primary treatment, secondary treatment, chlorination,
                    plus phosphate removal (lime coagulation, flocculation,
                    settling, recarbonation and filtration).
          Case 5.   Primary treatment, secondary treatment, phosphate re-
                    moval, chlorination, plus nitrogen removal (ammonia
                    stripping).
          Case 6.   Primary treatment, secondary treatment, phosphate re-
                    moval, nitrogen removal, chlorination plus activated
                    carbon absorption.
                                   45

-------
        The inclusion of a sufficiently large number of treatment
processes will result in a "smooth" continuous functional relation-
ship.   Realistically,  however, there would be a range of cost figures
for each strategy considered because of variations in size, efficiency
and a variety of spatial economic and natural conditions.  The function
in Exhibit II-5 would therefore depict the average cost  of pollution
abatement.  Associated with the average cost curve would be both
an upper and a lower cost boundry.

        This relationship--cost by treatment strategy--must be
extended to be meaningful.  Water quality associated benefits
are functions of priority surface water quality and must be in some
way compared with costs of pollution abatement if a significant
management tool is to be developed.  The relationship  depicted in
Exhibit II-5 must,  therefore,  be extended.  The  relationship that is
required is to establish the cost of pollution abatement as a function
of water quality rather than degree of control or percent treatment.

       Although difficult to acquire or formulate, such a transfer-
mation is essential.  The above mentioned Bramer study implicitly
assumes"some" unspecified  relationship between treatment strategy
or percent effluent removal  and resulting surface water quality.  With-
out the transformation—either implicit or explicit--it is impossible
to determine the benefits to  be gained from the inauguration of pollu-
tion abatement standards.  The benefits in the Bramer approach are cost
reductions and increased recreational water usage resulting from pollu-
tion abatement.  It is therefore essential to know the relationship between
various treatment strategies and  resulting water quality improvement.
The required relationship is not easily ascertained in that the  removal
of a certain percentage of effluent or pollution load by point pollution
source does not result in the same  percentage reduction in effluents
in surface water bodies.  The interaction of nonpoint pollution sources
and assimilative capacity complicates the problem and requires making
the relationship between percent treatment or percent effluent removal
at discharge points and resulting water quality explicit rather than im-
plicit.  For example,  in  some basins it is not inconceivable that a 100
percent reduction in point source pollutants would result in zero benefits
due to the  overwhelming  importance of nonpoint pollutant sources.
Knowledge of the influent and effluent load,  assimilative capacity,
treatment  efficiency and concentration and distribution of nonpoint
pollution sources--both man-made  and  natural--is required to establish
such a relationship.

        The need for this required relationship has been recognized
by the Environmental Protection Agency in The Economics of Clean
Water as is indicated by the following material:

                             46

-------
            The pollution source allocation is intended to pro-
            duce a picture of the relative contributions of var-
            ious activities that are pollution sources (note that
            not all activities or waste discharges necessarily
            result in pollution, as defined) to the situation re-
            flected in the index.  Previous efforts to establish
            such a ranking were  hindered by a lack of corres-
            pondence of source contributions with geographically
            unique indicators  of the resulting stream pollution
            and its effects. In addition to offering progress to
            the goal of associating discharges with pollution im-
            pacts, the present approach provides a means of un-
            ambiguously aggregating measures of source contri-
            butions to meet higher level planning information
            needs.(  4)

       For conceptual purposes  the above transformation function
is hypothesized in Exhibit II-6.

       It must be  recognized  that as the  influent and effluent
loads or treatment efficiencies change, the transformation
function would also be altered.  However, once the transfor-
mation function is established, it enables the conversion of cost
of pollution abatement as a function of percent of treatment to
cost of pollution abatement as a function of water quality.
Benefits of Pollution Abatement
        The benefits to be derived from pollution abatement are
 in the realm of cost and damage reductions as well as increases
 in water related activities,  i. e. ,  shifting demand as a result of
 water quality enhancement.   As water quality deteriorates, dam-
 ages and costs are incur red--damages to tangible and intangible
 assets, reduced efficiency,  additional production costs  to on-going
 activities and reduced potential benefits emanating from foregone
 activities.  The last economic  cost of pollution is the opportunity
 cost associated with water quality deterioration.  (The term pollu-
 tion as used herein refers to the use of surface waters for waste
 disposal to the  extent that the resulting water quality is less than
 natural water quality would  be  in the absence of such practices.)
 All of these economic costs must be  uniquely associated with
 specific water quality measures.

                              47

-------
        Exhibit II-6.  Water quality and percent treatment
Water
Quality
Charac-
teristic
                                                        Degree of Control
                                      48

-------
       The first category--additional production costs and re-
duced efficiency of productive inputs--is perhaps the easiest to
visualize.  One  of the major determinants of the value of water
is its contribution as a productive input. In general this is the
sole determinant of the value of water — if one includes both pro-
ductive uses and non-productive uses  such as esthetic appreci-
ation.  As the presence of foreign substances increase in concen-
tration, the efficiency of the productive input is  reduced.  If the
particular pollutant can be easily removed by conventional treat-
ment techniques, the inherent qualities  of water can be restored.
If not the result is reduced efficiency of a productive input.  In
either case the  result is the same—increased cost either because
of increased preuse treatment or reduced efficiency.   There is,
therefore,  a positive relationship between value of water in pro-
ductive processes and water quality and an inverse relationship
between production costs and water quality.

       The  same type of relationship exists between water quality
and water quality induced damages.  Hardness,  corrosion,  sedi-
mentation and numerous other pollutants are the source of large
amounts  of physical damages to productive, nonproductive, natural
or man-made  assets.

       The  last pollution cost category is the opportunity cost of
foregone activity as a  result of water pollution.  These are not
damages or increased production costs to on-going activities but
rather the opportunity cost of potential  activities that must be
foregone because of environmental degradation.  These opportunity
costs as  well as all of the  above mentioned costs also have an in-
verse  relationship to water quality.

       These relationships--economic costs of pollution--are
depicted in Exhibit II-7.   The abscissa of the graph is a composite
water quality measure with the zero coordinate representing the
area water quality that would prevail in the total absence of con-
trol.  The right hand point where the total cost curve  intersects
the horizontal axis would  represent the prevailing water quality
if all pollutants other than natural pollutants were eliminated.
At this point the composite economic cost of pollution curve would
be zero, since  by definition pollution (as  defined herein) is not
present.  The height of the curve at any water quality to the left
of the natural water quality would represent the economic costs of
pollution.   By considering numerous beneficial uses with varying
damage  thresholds  the smooth curves depicted  in Exhibit II-7 would
 result from the vertical summation of  individual component cost
curves.
                             49

-------
Exhibit II-7.  Economic costs of pollution
                    Total Economic Costs of Pollution

                            Opportunity Costs

                                Damage Costs
                                    •Reduced efficiency and
                                      increased production costs
                                      Water Quality Characteristics
                       50

-------
       The precise relationship and magnitude of these economic
costs of pollution are presently unknown but it is not unrealistic
to hypothesize the relationship as portrayed.

       The construction of the composite economic cost of pollution
function would have to proceed on a beneficial use by specific pollu-
tant basis for a  specific geographical area recognizing the area
water use and production specialties and other area and  economic
characteristics. As water quality is  improved, the benefits de-
rived are in the avoidance of a portion of the above mentioned costs
and damages. Alternatively, if flexible abatement standards are
imposed with the intent of maintaining a  stable water quality over
time, the economic gain is the potential  damages or costs that
would be avoided by further water quality degradation.  The
damage and cost avoidance or benefit function is depicted in
Exhibit II-8.

       The required comparability of benefits and costs is realized--
benefits  (cost and damage avoidance)  and cost of pollution abatement,
are both a function of water quality--thereby instilling some economic
meaning to otherwise sterile relationships. While the above modifi-
cation and extensions have perhaps filled some of the  voids in the
typical benefit cost approaches  to water  quality management, there
are several observations that are'perhaps in order at this time.

       1.  The  objective--perhaps secondary objective—of estab-
           lising a method capable of ascertaining an optimal area
           water quality has been realized by establishing benefits
           and  costs as a function of water quality as opposed to
           degree of treatment.

       2.  The difficulties encountered  in estimating indirect,
           intangible benefits have not,  in anyway, been diminished.
           Such benefits must be calculated if a benefit cost ratio
           close to unity is to be realized.

       3.   The procedure must still be  applied to many individual
           areas due  to the spatial variation of natural, physical
           and  economic characteristics and can not be satisfactorily
            generalized.
                             51

-------
     Exhibit II-8.  Total water quality benefits
Total
Benefits
           Zero Control
      100 Percent
      Control
Water Quality Characteristics
                                52

-------
       Now that the benefit cost approach has been reviewed and
refined,  it is perhaps expedient to embark on a brief evaluation
procedure to ascertain if the above approach will produce socially
optimal results.  It is useful to recall that Phase I concluded that
benefit cost analysis is  not an appropriate procedure to be used
in evaluating the impacts of water quality degradation.  This con-
clusion was based on a  general equilibrium versus partial equili-
brium approach and is forcefully conveyed by the following question:

            When a public  investment program results in major
            structural changes in the national economy or some
            regional economy, and when, as a consequence,  sig-
            nificant changes occur in the price  structure, benefit
            cost analyses is not applicable.  ( 5 )

       Given the previously emphasized point that general equilibrium
analysis has not been developed to an implementational stage, partial
equilibrium techniques  must be utilized as a first approximation to the
problem.  The question that arises is that now  that we have been com-
mitted to partial equilibrium analysis (duly recognizing the  limitations
of partial analysis), how can the problem best be formulated?  Is
the best framework benefit cost analysis?  Is benefit cost analysis
even applicable?  Are there other methods that are perhaps better
suited to the problem at hand?

        To  successfully answer these problems, a few benefit cost
 conventions must be recognized.  T.he first convention is that the
 objective of benefit cost analysis is to assist in achieving economic
 efficiency or maximization of net social welfare.  ( 6 ) The second
 convention is that the feasibility of the proposed investment be eval-
 uated on the basis of the estimated net benefits.   "The benefit cost
 criterion dictates that the investment program be chosen which maxi-
 mizes net benefits, subject to the constraint that  net benefits are
 positive."  ( 7 )  The second  convention clearly indicates that the
 normal usage of benefit cost analysis as described by the above
 references does not normally allow for the maximization of net
 negative benefits or minimization of net costs even in the event
 of investment projects  involves numerous intangible and unquanti-
 fiable benefits that can not be assessed.
                               53

-------
       The question of whether actual benefits exceed cost becomes
rather academic.  Many contend that if all intangible benefits were
accurately calculated,  the benefits of water quality enhancement would
greatly exceed the costs of water pollution abatement.  This is purely
academic in that no one has yet been able to develop a satisfactory
benefit estimation technique.   "While early results of recreation
evaluation studies suggest that such analyses can be successfully
done in certain instances and we can expect in the future they will
provide us with usable  damage functions,  routine detailed measure-
ment of recreational damage  is not now possible."   ( 8 )  Is benefit
cost--given the state-of-the-arts of benefit estimation--an adequate
analytical technique applicable to the  task at hand?  If benefit esti-
mation is not capable of accurately assessing public preferences, then
alternative techniques should be explored, and secondly to briefly
hypothesize on the true social preferences. The following items and/or
excerpts from  summaries of  previous studies shed some light on
whether one can realistically expect estimated water quality assoc-
iated benefits to exceed pollution abatement costs.
       1.  Bramer estimated a benefit cost ratio of 0.85 for the
           Ohio River Basin.

       2.  Matson estimated a benefit cost ratio of 0.96 for the
           Maumee River.

       3.  "Several studies have been models of ingenuity in using
           limited data and modelling or  similating effects on in-
           dustry operations. Some  studies are available for the
           petroleum refining, fruit and vegetable canning,  thermal
           power,  and beet sugar industries. In all of these in-
           stances, industrial costs turn out to be surprisingly
           insensitive to intake water quality within comparatively
           wide ranges--especially in regard to aspects of quality
           that are usually influenced by  prior uses and discharge
           of effluents."  ( 9 )

       4.  "The  situation is surprisingly similar for municipal
           water supplies.  Much of what has been said about the
           need for high  water quality supplies as a basis for
           preparation of potable water is more .the product of
           emotion than  of logic. "  (10 )
                             54

-------
 5.   "Poor quality water does impose extra costs on munic-
     ipal water systems but—except in cases of toxic or
     evil-tasting substances--use by  municipalities ordinarily
     cannot justify high levels of waste effluent control."  (11)

 6.   "The limited evidence from the  studies and  analysis
     discussed above leads to the virtually inescapable con-
     clusion that high water quality rmist be justified pri-
     marily on aesthetic and recreational  grounds,  if it is
     to be justified  at all.  This conclusion is reinforced
     by the results  of the Delaware estuary study."   (12)

 7.   "The benefits  of raw water quality improvement which
     could be identified as accruing to municipal and indus-
     trial water users were very small compared with the
     cost of improvement. "  (13)

 8.   "The annual value of the estimated loss due to shifts
     in the demand for angling in Yaquina  Bay amounted
     to  about $63,000.  This is  less than the capital cost
     (but excluding annual operating costs) of a basic sewage
     treatment plant for a comparatively small city."  (14)

 9.   Preliminary estimates of water quality associated
     health impacts suggests  that an  annual rate of only 1. 1
     water borne illnesses per  100,000 population can be di-
     rectly attributed to surface water quality degradation. (15)

10.   Viral infectious hepatitis can be transmitted by water
     routes, although this is  rare.  (16)

11.   Several studies indicate  that untreated groundwater and
     not surface water has been the most  frequent cause of
     recent gastro-enteritis and diarrhea and not surface
     water degradation.  (17)

12.   Preliminary estimates of domestic damages resulting
     from water of questionable quality indicates that the
     private wells  are the major source of such damages.
     A  large portion of the remainder of the damages that
     are attributable to surface water impairment are the
     result of hardness and mineralization that are present
     in varying degrees in water in its native state.  Removal
     of such pollutants would require extensive and perhaps
     unreasonable  treatment  costs.
                        55

-------
       13.   Most of the previous studies have been in areas that
            can not be considered typical of the nation as a whole
            such as the Delaware estuary,  Potomac River,  Ohio
            River or  the Miami Basin which are highly industralized
            or population centers that already face severe water
            quality problems.  These area studies result in signi-
            ficant benefit estimates.

       14.   Very few if any of the above studies have  considered
            substitution effects which would further reduce the
            national water quality associated benefits.  (On the
            other hand, neither have most  studies considered all
            types of benefits expected.)

       The above items and excerpts indicate that health, production,
and municipal users can not be considered to be the source  of large
benefits  of water quality improvement.  It  therefore appears that the
only way pollution abatement measures can be justified in a benefit
cost framework is  through the accurate assessment of recreation
and esthetic benefits--which is not possible at the present time.  The
use of benefit cost analysis as a water quality management tool can not
on the basis of the  above excerpts,  be expected to result in positive
national  net benefits for the following reasons:

       1.   Inability to accurately measure and assess intangible
            and indirect benefits.

       2.   Other least cost techniques such as preuse chlorina-
            tion effectively reduce many of the adverse water
            quality associated impacts.

       3.   Consideration of substitution effects will  substantially
            reduce a  significant portion of  the total water quality
            associated impacts.

       4.   The benefits, as normally defined, are not of the magni-
            tude as frequently hypothesized.

       The question that arises is in reference to how the true
social objectives can best be served. If the public decision
would be to inaugurate pollution abatement investment even if
the benefit cost ratio is less than unity then we can conclude that
                               56

-------
benefit cost analysis is not appropriate perhaps for the reason
that we can not accurately assess or assign values to intangible
benefits and public preferences in general. (18)  Why then must the
water quality management problem be cast in a benefit cost frame-
work and is there an alternative that circumvents the undesirable
features of this type of analysis? In addition, there may be other
reasons why alternative methods may be preferred.
E.   An Alternative Approach

       By couching the water quality management in an alternative con-
ceptual framework, some of the difficulties can be avoided.  This
setting is a cost minimization approach where costs include both
treatment costs and damage costs, e.g.,  damages, efficiency
costs and opportunity costs.  This is desirable for several reasons
some of which are listed below:

        1.   As is  stated in Managing Water Quality;  Economics,
            Technology, Institutions^by Kneese and Bower, "cost
            minimization . . . calls attention to the fact that water
            quality management is essentially a matter of cost
            avoidance."

        2.   It also calls attention to and assists in deriving an
            optimum result in that it minimizes the overall costs
            associated with waste disposal activity.

        3.   Since  the primary source of the pollution problem stems
            from  externalities or avoidance of on-site costs,  the
            proper approach is  to consider and minimize all costs
            (both  on-site and off-site costs).  This is a significant
            step in the internalization  of external costs.

        4.   Certain natural  resources  are considered common
            property resources belonging to the society in general.
            The use of these resources as disposal system results
            in a cost savings to producers but more importantly a
            value reduction  or a cost to society in general.  There
            seems to be a basic inconsistency or incongruency
            associated with  inflicting damage  to a publicly owned
            common property resource and subsequently calling the
                                57

-------
            results of corrective measures a social benefit and
            further basing the feasibility of these corrective
            measures on highly questionable benefit estimates.
            This benefit misnomer and the resulting temptation
            of using a highly structured benefit cost framework
            which may not be capable of producing socially optimal
            results is eliminated by adopting a  cost minimization
            approach.

        5.  The use of benefit cost analysis inevitably results in
            comparing derived water quality associated benefit
            cost ratio with benefit cost ratios derived for other
            proposed public investment projects.  In view of the
            fact that an accurate assessment of water quality
            associated benefits can not be achieved  at the present
            time and the public desires pollution abatement mea-
            sures this may not be desirable in that it is  quite likely
            that the derived water quality associated benefit cost
            ratios will be  relatively low and may never be of suf-
            ficient relative magnitude to justify additional pollu-
            tion abatement investment.   It is therefore desirable to
            disassociate pollution abatement programs from other
            possible public investment projects by recognizing the
            fact that pollution abatement programs are necessary
            and seek out least cost methods of minimizing the total
            costs of waste disposal associated with producing a given
            quantity of goods.

        6.   The last point--while very subjective and  opinionated--
            is that there may be less reluctance to include estimates
            of intangible and somewhat uncertain pollution impacts
            in a least cost framework than in the standard benefit
            cost framework.

        In summary, the above  items indicate some  advantages to
be gained by formulating the  problem in a cost minimization frame-
work.   This framework is easier to  conceptualize and therefore  has
considerable merit.  If the public desires pollution abatement meas-
ures even at some material sacrifice let us recognize this desire
and formulate the problem  so as to minimize the problem of total
waste disposal.
                             58

-------
       The construction of the total cost of pollution function must
consider both on-site and off-site disposal costs.  The off-site
(economic costs of pollution) costs are the economic costs of
pollution that vary  inversely with the level of water quality.  In
the total absence of control,  the economic costs of pollution  are
at a maximum and  alternatively at the level of total control,  the
economic costs  of pollution are zero as portrayed earlier in
Exhibit II-7.   The second component of total social cost  of pollu-
tion is the cost of pollution abatement as presented earlier in
Exhibit II-5.   These components and the corresponding total cost
curve are depicted in Exhibit II-8.  The social objective can be
maximized by selecting the water quality level which minimizes the
total waste disposal cost such as point A in  Exhibit II-9.

       The expressed preference for the cost minimization approach
places the problem in its proper conceptual setting but does  not in
any way  complicate or add to the  required estimation problems.
The economic cost of pollution must be established in both the
cost minimization and the benefit cost framework. The  costs of
pollution abatement must also be established regardless of the
analytical framework.  The transformation  function relating degree
of treatment and resulting water quality must be considered  in both
procedures.   The only difference is in the way one views and inter-
prets the final results.  Since the cost minimization procedure is
preferred, the terminology from this point on will reflect this pre-
ference  (the  benefit associated with water quality enhancement are
properly referred to as reductions in the economic costs of  pollution),

        Before proceeding to the following chapters it must  again
 be emphasized  that as long as  only partial  estimates of the  economic
 cost of pollution are available  any analytical framework will be
 deficient in  deriving socially optimum results.  The framework that
 approaches  the problem in the most straight-forward manner con-
 sistent with the nature of the problem is desired however.  In this
 regard  cost minimization is  preferred.


        The following sections are devoted to a further discussion
 of the estimation procedures and techniques that are required to
 establish the above cost curves.  Since the estimation procedures
 are essentially the same as would be required in a benefit cost
 framework,  Sections  III and IV are rather brief and general.
 Section  V does, however, discuss at some  length required exten-
 sions that have  not been as of this time presented in water quality
 management literature.

                             59

-------
            Exhibit II-9.  Total cost of waste disposal.
Total
Cost of
Pollu-
tion
                                                       Total cost
Economic cost of
pollution abatement
                                                 Economic cost of pollution
                                                       Water Quality Characteristics
                                       60

-------
                         Footnotes


 (1)  Bramer, H. C., "The  Economic Aspects of the Water Pollu-
     tion Abatement Program in the Ohio^River Valley," Doctoral
     Dissertation, University of Fittsburg,  I960.

 (2)  Mat son, J., Cost of Industrial and Municipal Water Pollution
     Abatement ir^the Maumee River Basin, Master's Thesis,
     University of Toledo, 1968.

 (3)  Environmental Protection Agency, "The Economics of Clean
     Water,",  1972.

 (4)  Ibid. , Environmental Protection Agency, 1972.

 (5)  Lind, R. C., ''Benefit-Cost Analysis:  A Criterion for Social
     Investment," Campbell and Sylvester (eds.) Water Resources
     Management and Public Policy, University of Washington Press,
     1968.

 (6)  Ibid. . R.  C. Lind

 (7)  Ibid. , R.  C. Lind

 (8)  Kneese, A. V. and B.  T. Bower,  Managing Water Quality:
     Economics, Technology, Institutions,  Resources for the
     Future, John Hopkins Press,  1968.

 (9)  Ibid., Kneese and Bower.

(10)  Ibid. , Kneese and Bower.

(11)  Ibid. , Kneese and Bower.

(12)  Ibid. , Kneese and Bower.

(13)  Ibid., Kneese and Bower.

(14)  Ibid. , Kneese and Bower.

(15)  Weibel, S. R., et al., Water Borne — Disease  Outbreaks, 1946-
     1960, Journal of the American Water Works Association,  1964.
                                61

-------
(16)    Wenk,  V. D. , A  Technology As^e^smentJMethodology, Water
       Pollution:  Domestic Wastes, The Mitre Corporation, 1971.

(17)    Ibid. ,  Wenk.

(18)    We feel that there is substantial evidence which indicates
       that the public indeed desires increased environmental
       protection and is willing to perhaps make some  material
       sacrifices to achieve this end.  If the state of the knowledge
       can not accurately measure this public desire and the public
       is willing to make a material sacrifice then it is a mistake
       to utilize benefit cost analysis as a decision making criterion.

(19)    Op. cit. , Kneese and Bower.
                                62

-------
                        SEC TION III

             ECONOMIC COST OF POLLUTION
A.   Multidimens tonality

         The successful estimation of the composite economic cost
of pollution function that was discussed in the previous chapter can
be achieved only by disaggregating the problem into manageable  seg-
ments.  The  multidimensionality of the problem prohibits tackling
the problem  in its entirety without further simplification.  The com-
posite function can be constructed only by considering the individual
components.   In effect this  requires disaggregation on at least three
levels,  i.e.,  specific beneficial uses, specific pollutants and a
geographical delineation.  The purpose herein is to briefly consider
the characteristics of the individual economic cost of pollution com-
ponents, and secondly, to elaborate on the procedure  required to
estimate individual pollution costs and finally to further discuss  a
meaningful aggregation  scheme so that the desired national estimates
can be derived, i. e. , aggregation of individual benefits to derive
composite area costs of pollution functions and aggregation of com-
posite area costs of pollution functions to achieve national estimates
and functions.
B.   Beneficial Use Classification

         The cost of pollution is incurred or borne by a variety
of water users--including both tangible and intangible water uses.
The economic  costs of pollution are therefore the damages, ef-
ficiency reductions, process changes, additional expenses  incurred
and the opportunity costs that are imposed on a variety of beneficial
uses.  The most logical method of assessing the economic  costs of
pollution is therefore  to consider each of these uses to estimate
the economic cost  of water quality degradation by user.

        A variety of taxonomies  have  been used in delineating uses
with each scheme  tailored to best serve and facilitate the immediate
objectives at hand. The scheme adopted in the state-of-the-art review
considered four broad beneficial use  areas--health,  production,  esthet-
ics and  ecology.  While this  scheme does not succeed in establishing
completely unique  categories totally absent of interdependence,  it does
successfully isolate major beneficial uses under separate headings or
divisions.  Health includes all human health water quality associated
impacts.  Production includes all industrial, municipal and domestic
                             63

-------
water usage.  Esthetics includes all esthetic considerations that are
directly or indirectly associated with water usage while ecological
considerations include all natural water uses that directly or in-
directly effect a variety of natural (ecosystem) functions.  Each
of these broad groupings can be further divided into many sub-
divisions.  Exhibit HI-1 presents a representative listing of bene-
ficial uses and the water quality impacts that can be associated with
each beneficial use.

        Each of these beneficial uses depend on and use water in a
variety of specialized ways and only by considering the detrimental
impacts of increased pollutant concentrations on each of these uses
can the true social cost of water quality degradation be ascertained.
 C.  Economic Costs of Pollution
         A delineation of beneficial uses is only the starting point
 in that the costs of pollution to each use may consist of various
 types of costs.  These costs may take the form of damages to
 natural or man-made assets,  increased production expenses, re-
 duced efficiency or increases in opportunity costs. Only by con-
 sidering all of the costs of pollution can the true economic cost
 of water quality degradation be ascertained.  A brief description
 of the various types of damages are listed and briefly described
 in Exhibit III-2.

         Since the economic costs of pollution are dependent on
 beneficial use, an aggregate water quality measure is meaningless
 in that use is  specialized and  the cost of pollution incurred emanates
 from the presence of specific undesirable water quality constituents,
 i.e. , the presence of toxic  substances significantly impairs the value
 of water used for human consumption but has no conceivable effect
 on other water uses such as the production of primary metals.  The
 potential gain to be realized from belaboring the argument beyond
 this point is minimal so in summary it is sufficient to conclude that
 the cost of pollution function must by necessity be constructed by
 considering numerous uses, various costs  and a variety of specific
 pollutants.  By considering the costs of pollution by specific  pollu-
 tants and beneficial uses, the most damaging pollutants can be iso-
 lated and this in turn is expected to provide further insight into possible
                             64

-------
Exhibit III-1.  Beneficial use classifications and specific impacts
                        of water pollution
Use Classification
  I.   Health
 II.   Production
      A.  Municipal water use
          Domestic water use
          Industrial water use
          including the following
          industrial groups:

          Food and Kindred
            Products
          Textile Mill Products
          Lumber
          Paper
          Chemicals
          Petroleum and Coal
          Rubber
          Leathe r
          Stone, Clay and Glass
          Primary Metals
          Electrical Equipment
          Transportation Equipment
           Specific Impact

All water quality related diseases.
For a listing of water related diseases
refer to  Table I of health section,
Appendix B.
Increased preuse treatment cost as a
result of water quality deterioration,
i.e. ,  additional expenditure for softening
iron and manganese removal,  chlori-
nation, corrosion control,  taste and odor
control, and filtration above and beyond
what would be required to utilize water
in its natural state.

Increased use of water softeners,  deter-
gents,  soaps, increased plumbing costs
(pipes, water heaters, etc.) and in-
creased use of bottled water for drinking
purposes.

Softening,  iron and manganese removal,
chlorination, taste and odor control,
and filtration. Reduced heat transfer
rates because of scaling and fouling of
heat transfer surfaces and reduced
equipment life because of corrosion,
and other undesirable impacts stemming
from excessive effluent loads.
                              65

-------
Exhibit III-1  (continued)
Use Classification

      D.  Commercial fishing
      E.
A gricultural water use
(1) Animal production
          (Z) Plant production
      F.  Navigation water use
          Thermal-electric and
          hydro-electric power
          generation water use
      H.  Federal installation
      I.   Transportation
      Specific Impact

Decreased fish yield and increased
production costs as a result of water
quality degradation. Increased main-
tenance and repair costs of commercial
vessels and supporting equipment.

Increased animal production costs as
a result of contaminated food supplies,
death and alteration of psychological
function,  reduced  daily gains and in-
creased cost of health control measures.

Increased production costs due to crop
failures, yield restrictions or marketing
constraints as a result of increased man-
made effluent loads.

Excessive corrosion and maintenance
on all water craft. Channel maintenance
dredging and acid  mine  damage to navi-
gational support equipment resulting from
excessive effluent flows.

Increased repair maintenance and
damages to power generation equip-
ment, reservoirs  and dams as  a  re-
sult of increased effluent loads.

Impact for federal installation  include
increased preuse treatment and increased
physical damages  resulting from use of
water possessing undesirable con-
stituents .

Impact for transportation include re-
duced efficiency, damage to equipment
and increased preuse treatment directly
related to man-made pollutants.
                             66

-------
Exhibit III-l  (continued)
Use Classification

      J.  Other production
III.   Esthetic
IV.   Ecological
      Specific Impact

Other damages, reduced efficiency and
additional expenses incurred to other
production processes not specifically
mentioned  above.

Reduced esthetic appreciation, property
value reductions and  reduced potential
for travel and reductions in water  based
recreational activities and expenditures
as a result of reduced human esthetic
appreciation resulting from undesirable
water quality constituents.

The disruptions of vital life support
cycles and systems resulting in unknown
and unpredictable social, economic and
ecological consequences.
                                67

-------
          Exhibit III-2.  Economic costs of pollution
Type

Dama ge s
Increased Production Expenses
and/or Reduced Efficiency
Environmental Risk
Opportunity Costs
     Description and Illustration

Physical damages and  reduced value of
resources as a result of undesirable water
quality constituents.  This includes  many
types of damages to a large number of
resources, i. e. , both  natural and man-
made, which are directly or indirectly
effected by man-made  pollutants.

Many types of preuse production expenses
and/or process changes  necessitated by
water quality degradation are illustrative
of this impact.  In addition, there are
some water quality variables that cannot
be removed by conventional treatment
strategies or are present in only minor
concentrations that are not treated but
still impair the value of water to some
degree by reducing the efficiency  of water
as a productive input.

An indirect, and often  times intangible
cost of pollution stems from the uncertain^
of damages which might occur following
environmental degradation.  Costs of
avoidance of environmental risk and pre-
cautionary measures are thus  economic
costs of pollution.

In addition to the above damages,  in-
creased production expenses,  efficiency
reductions and risks there are other
economic costs  of pollution.  These take
the form of opportunities lost or inability
to utilize, develop or appreciate various
natural resources.  This loss  or perhaps
potential loss  is the part of the opportunity
cost of pollution.  This category is  net of
the other above mentioned economic costs-
It further includes the  option and latent
demand concepts.
                              68

-------
pollution abatement strategies by isolating the major sources and
further dictates the treatment strategy required.  Appendix  C
presents a variety of important pollutants and groups of pollutants,
the major source  of these pollutants,  possible damages incurred
from excessive concentrations and treatment required to elim-
inate these pollutants.

         The complication that is encountered is that each use
may realistically  be dependent on several water quality variables.
For example, water used for contact  recreation purposes should
meet several quality  requirements--fecal coliform, temperature
clarity, floatable  oil,  suspended solids and odor requirements.
For this reason multivariate  functions may have to be developed
or alternatively simplified function relating economic cost of
pollution to selected key variables may be  used as a first approxi-
mation of the functional relationships  between cost of pollution
and water quality. Significant inroads have been made in the area
of relating water use requirements to key water quality variables.
A variety of well established  critical  levels and damage thresholds
have been established and are presented in Appendix D for selected
water uses.  These critical levels and damage thresholds will have
to be considered in assessing water quality associated  impacts in
that exceeding the critical level or damage threshold will result in
increased costs,  increased damages  or perhaps complete elimin-
ation of the beneficial use.
Estimation Procedure
         The above mentioned multidimensionality,  variations in
data availability and data form and variations in functional form
of the hypothesized relationships prohibits prescribing a single
technique applicable to the estimation of all economic costs  of
pollution.  The estimation procedure must be tailored to the speci-
fic characteristics of individual water quality associated impacts.
The procedure  required,  regardless  of the type of analysis, or
irrespective of the beneficial use under consideration is to ascer-
tain the additional cost incurred as a result of water quality de-
gradation.  In many cases this will, in effect,  require a complete
analysis of the  cost determinants or independent variables affecting
water using activities at several water quality levels.  Only by
observing costs and participation rates at several water quality
                           69

-------
levels can the economic costs  of pollution abatement be ascertained.
"Before and after" examples incorporating demand analysis,  regres-
sion analysis, option demand,  participation rates, percentage reduc-
tions and  cost variations are relevant methods,  techniques and con-
cepts useful in assessing the economic costs of pollution.  The most
descriptive method of portraying such cost estimation procedures is
to do so by using several illustrative examples that have been used  in
previous attempts to quantify the economic costs of pollution.  The
basic goal of all of these techniques is to delineate the independent
variables affecting water usage so as  to allocate the portion of total
costs that can be correctly associated with water quality degradation.
It would be desirable to delve into  specific techniques that might be
utilized in Phase III, but until  specific areas of further study  have been
selected,  it is not desirable to devote a large amount of effort to such
tasks.  The following discussion is therefore rather general and is
valuable for illustrative purposes only.
Costs of Pollution and Municipal Preuse Water Treatment Costs

       The cost of preuse municipal water treatment is determined
by numerous physical and economic spatially dependent variables.
The important municipal preuse treatment independent cost variables
are listed below:

       1.   Prevailing treatment strategy
       2.   Capacity of the system
       3.   Utilization of the system
       4.   Ownership of the system
       5.   Regional wage rates
       6.   Age of the institutions
       7.   Cost of variable inputs
       8.   Concentration and type of effluents

       Municipal preuse water  treatment costs should involve allow-
ances for both man-made point  source emissions and natural pollu-
tants which are present  in prevailing water sources.   The appro-
priate treatment strategy and the consequent cost of pollution
attributable to man-made sources may be derived from a total cost
of treatment relationship as follows.  Given the prevailing regional
                           70

-------
wage rates and the other appropriate spatially dependent exogenous
variables,  the cost of preuse municipal treatment strategies in the
absence of manmade pollutants can be ascertained.  Incremental
municipal preuee treatment costs that are incurred as a result of
increased effluent loads can justifiably be classified as the economic
costs of pollution.  These may take  the form of increased operation
and maintenance costs as a result of increased effluent loads or in-
creased capital costs associated with more advanced and sophisti-
cated treatment strategies necessitated by the introduction of man-
made pollutants.

       The preuse municipal average cost curve  for a given area
is the envelop curve associated with a variety of constituent indi-
vidual cost curves each applicable to specific treatment strategies
required to reduce effluent loads associated with  specific water
qualities.  The envelop curve and the constituent  curves are de-
picted in Exhibit HI-3.

       Several observations are in  order at this juncture.  At some
point in the above  hypothesized relationship, the cost of preuse
municipal treatment would reach a minimum,  indicating that some
preuse treatment costs would be incurred regardless of the pre-
vailing water quality.  Chlorination, filtration and other treatment
processes  are essential irrespective of the prevailing water quality.
The reason for this distinction is that the economic cost of pollution
is represented by the portion of the curve above and to the left of
the minimum cost point.  For example, if the water quality free of
man-made pollutants is determined to be water quality B in Exhibit
IU-3, the true cost of pollution is the height of the curve at every
point less  the quantity BC.  The  cost of municipal preuse treatment
curve can  therefore be converted to an economic  cost of pollution
curve simply by shifting the ordinate upward by a distance equal to
the cost of preuse municipal treatment in the absence of man-made
pollutants  such as point D in Exhibit III-3.
                             71

-------
  CO

  O

  U





  <0
      Exhibit III-3.  Economic coat of pollution in reference to


                    municipal preuae treatment.
3 fl»
*§
+>  fl)
0)  LI
O  o.
O
  ^H
U  IT)


It
0 .H


s§  D

w H
                                                                 Treatment

                                                                 Strategy 1
                                                           B   Water Quality


                                                               Characteristics
                                 72

-------
       The estimation of the entire function would be desirable
but time consuming task.  The required level of effort can be
substantially reduced by considering only two points, one, the
cost of treatment associated with the prevailing water quality and
the second is the costs associated with treating water in its natural
state.  For a first approximation,  such simplifications are not
unrealistic.  The above endeavors  are not unrealistic in that cost
data for municipal preuse treatment plants are quite accessible.
Essentially what has been described is a "before  and after" example
with the difference  being attributed to increased effluent loads and
lower quality of surface  water withdrawn.
 Estimating Recreation Impacts^of Water Quality Degradation

       Other estimates of the economic costs of pollution are also
 available in the literature.  Few, however, are as straightforward
 as the above municipal preuse treatment example.  One example of
 an attempt to estimate the recreation impacts  of pollution is pre-
 sented in the well publicized Delaware Estuary Study.  ( 1 )  The
 estimation procedure incorporated multivariate regression analysis
 to isolate  the critical variables influencing participation in water
 based recreational activities.  Exhibit III-4 presents the socio-
 economic  and locational variables that were used to determine the
 important independent factors  influencing participation rates in
 various water based recreational activities.

       From this information recreational probability of participation
 equations  were formulated.  Once the equations were established
 appropriate values of the  relevant exogenous variables were com-
 puted and applied to determine the corresponding value of the de-
 pendent variable.  This in effect establishes total participants prior to
 water quality improvement for the benefit considered.  The next step
 was to assume that some water quality improvement would subse-
 quently enhance the  rating of fishing facilities (FPS) from previous
 levels to higher levels.  With the improvement in the FPS new pro-
 bability and usage functions were developed.  A comparison of the
 usage rates with quality improvement with the previous unimproved
 usage rates revealed that a significant increase in usage results
 from water quality improvement.  This difference is  the cost of in-
 creased effluent loads.  This represents another method of establishing
 the costs  of pollution--economic costs  in the sense of opportunity costs
 of foregone usage.   There are numerous other examples of previous

                             73

-------
  Exhibit III-4.   Recreation participation variables.
                Variable            Symbol

      Age                            A
      Income                         Y
      Sex                            5

      Education                       E
      Race                           R

      Life cycle                       L\

                                     L,

      Urbanization (belt)               U

      Occupation                      O

      Region                         G

      Participates in fishing             FP

      Participates in swimming          SP

      Participates in boating            DP

      Water per capita                 W

      Expert rating or swimming facili-    SFS
        ties in primary sampling unit
      Expert rating of fishing facilities    FPS
        in primary sampling unit
      Coastal area presence             C
              Description

discrete midpoint values of class intervals
discrete midpoint values of class intervals
0 if female
1 if male
1 if grade school highest attainment
2 if high school highest attainment
3 if college highest attainment
0 if non-white
1 if white
0 if no children in household
1 if children in household
0 if no children over 5 years old
1 if children over 5 years old
0 if urban location
1 if suburban or outlying location
0 if blue collar
1 if white collar
0 if Northeast or North Central
1 if West or South
0 if non-participant
1 if participant
0 if non-participant
1 if participant
0 if non-participant
1 if participant
area of sport fishing  water per capita by
  state, 1960
discrete values of 1 through 5

discrete values of 1 through 5

0 inland area
1 coastline or Great Lakes present
Source:   Allen V.  Kneese  and  Stephen  C. Smith,  (ed.),  Water Research
             p.   193.                                                          	'	
                                              74

-------
attempts to establish the cost of pollution as a function of water quality.
These include establishing soap and detergent purchases, crop yields,
property value charges, maintenance costs, domestic damages, and
other damages to appropriate water quality levels.  Each attempt
must essentially isolate and determine the important cost and usage
independent variables and assess the portion of the  total that can be
attributed to increased  effluent loads.  As was initially stated at the
beginning of this chapter, the precise technique and analytical pro-
cedures incorporated must be tailored to the specific use under con-
sideration.  One additional  illustration of estimating procedure and
consideration involved in estimating health impacts is presented in
the health section  in Appendix D.
 D.  Aggregation

       The problem of aggregation is intrinsic to the construction
 of national pollution cost estimates.  There are several levels at
 which the problem is encountered.  First,  individual beneficial
 use pollution functions are established and must be aggregated to
 achieve composite area  economic cost of pollution functions.  Since
 the ordinate or y axis is dollars per unit of water used, dollars
 per capita or cost per shoreline mile which can be  easily aggregated
 into meaningful regional totals if a composite multivariate measure
 is depicted on the abscissa.

       The  second level of aggregation, i.e. , region by region
 aggregation of composite functions, must proceed on the same
 general basis.  The many complications and complexities that
 are likely  to be encountered in aggregation are recognized but
 not developed at this point.  A more effective place and time
 for such a discussion would be after regional cost estimates
 have been  established and a better appreciation and understanding
 of the aggregation problem is achieved.
                            75

-------
E.  Summary

       Many attempts to estimate the economic costs of pollution
to specific beneficial uses are present in the literature.

Each method must be sensitive to the specific characteristics of
the beneficial use under consideration.   The estimation of the
national costs associated with pollution must therefore seek out specific
examples and data sources which facilitate and expedite the analysis.
Extreme care must  be taken in extending regional estimates to national
estimates in view of the many and diversified regional water use
characteristics and  water quality requirements.
                               76

-------
                       Footnotes
(1)  Kneese, A. V. and Stephen (ed.) Water Research, Resources for
    the Future, Inc., John Hopkins Press.
                          77

-------
                        SEC TION IV

            COST OF POLLUTION ABATEMENT
A.   Introduction

        Estimating national pollution abatement costs has progressed
to an advanced state relative to the establishment of national benefit
functions.  The methodology is well established and little change is
needed.  There is,  however, substantial need  to further extend the
analysis to adequately portray the relationship between  pollution
abatement measures and resulting surface water quality.  This
extension is the  subject of Section V and will not be discussed
here.  In an attempt to be complete this brief chapter concerning
the cost of pollution abatement has been included.   We shall
first discuss the procedures utilized to establish the cost of pollu-
tion abatement function and  secondly, briefly summarize some of the
material from Appendix A.
B.   Procedures
        The general method of establishing national or regional
pollution abatement functions must proceed by considering indi-
vidual treatment strategies by pollution source.  A listing of pos-
sible strategies was presented in S^c^ion II.  Unfortunately it is
not possible at the present time to consider or establish a national
pollution abatement function considering all of the treatment  strategieg
listed.  The alternative is to establish the cost function by constructive
the cost of a few strategies assuming that all pollution  sources within
the region or country adopted a given strategy. This procedure is the
technique most frequently used in the partial equilibrium studies
reviewed.  Assuming varying treatment  strategies presents significant
data and estimation problems with respect to both costs and re-
sulting water  quality and will not be pursued further at  this point in that
this constitutes  a long run objective.  The simplifying assumption that
all pollution sources within a given basin adopt standard abatement
measures is realistic  in that isolated controls can not be expected
to significantly  reduce the total effluent load.  This assumption was
adopted by Bramer and justified on the following basis:
                            78

-------
            This type of isolated pollution abatement results
            in the  correction of local nuisance problems, but
            does not improve water quality so as to permit
            well-rounded water uses.  This was the basis upon
            which  the State of Ohio exempted its municipalities
            on the Ohio River from requirements of the install-
            ation of waste treatment facilities until those up-
            stream in other states took action.  It is  on the
            same basis that Pennsylvania has not required
            treatment facilities on streams  subject to acid
            mine drainage until a satisfactory solution to this
            problem is  found.  (1)

       By adopting similar assumptions  and limiting the  number
of possible  treatment strategies under consideration, the establish-
ment of regional or national pollution abatement functions would be
a relatively routine task.  Even though it would be  a  routine task
it would require an enormous amount of  data collection.  A similar
task--involving a complete assessment of present and projected
industrial waste treatment strategies--has been recently published
by the Environmental Protection Agency.

       In that it has been constantly emphasized throughout this
report that  the establishment of cost of pollution abatement functions
does  not represent the  area of greatest need, we will not belabor the
point further but will briefly recognize several limitations that
currently exist.
C.   Limiting Factors

       One major limitation is that given present state of the knowledge
constraints, it is difficult, if not impossible, to incorporate  nonpoint
pollution costs into such a framework, not because the framework is
deficient but "because estimates of nonpoint pollution load and treatment
costs have not been adequately developed.  It is also impossible to
relate cost of pollution abatement to national water quality in that
a meaningful national water quality estimate is not available  and  is
not meaningful due to the disparity of water quality levels.  This
further reinforces previous conclusions  that cost estimates are
meaningful only in reference to small hydrological areas in that
present aggregation methods  have not been adequately refined.
                              79

-------
       The current state of the knowledge with respect to pollu-
tion abatement costs can best be illustrated by summarizing some
of the information presented in Appendix A.
DA   National Pollution Abatement Cost Estimates

       From the material presented in Appendix A it is possible,
with only a few extensions , to develop national pollution abatement
cost estimates.   The estimates that are developed can not be re-
lated to water quality levels or  a variety of treatment strategies
but instead portray the cost of pollution abatement required to
meet current standards.  Industrial pollution abatement cost
estimates use in Appendix A are based on estimates provided in
the Economics of Clean Water which estimates the industrial cost
of achieving the  equivalent of secondary treatment as indicated by
the following excerpt from the same publication.

           What is the cost of wastewater treatment to U.S.
           industry assuming that industry must reach the
           equivalent of secondary wastewater treatment as
           stated in the Water  Pollution Control Act.  (2)

       Adopting the same assumptions for municipal treatment
costs,  i.e. , assuming all municipalities achieved the equivalent
of secondary treatment,  produced the total cost  figures as pre-
sented in Exhibit IV-1.  From the material in Exhibit IV-1 it is
possible to develop a preliminary national cost function relating
costs of pollution abatement to the prevailing water standards.

       Municipal and industrial water treatment cost for secondary
treatment on an annualized basis would be 3, 880 and 4, 562 million
for 1968 and  1976 respectively.  The question that immediately
comes to mind is how do these figures compare  with the possible
economic cost reductions that might be realized.  Unfortunately,
this can not be determined without first ascertaining the water
quality improvement that would be realized if  the equivalent of
secondary treatment were inaugurated.   This  general topic is
further discussed in Chapter V.
                             80

-------
00
     Exhibit rV-1.  Total capital, operating and maintenance costs required to meet current standards

                            in 1968 and 1976 (1967 dollars expressed in millions)

Municipal
Industrial
Total
1968
Required
capital
16,810
8,966
25,776
1968
Operating
and
maintenance
731
1,320
2,051
1968
Total
annualized
. */
costs _'

3,880
1976
Required
capital
19,382
10,752
30,134
1976
Operating
and
maintenance^
843
1,582
2,425
1976
Total
annualized
costs—

4,562
      */
      ~ All capital costs were annualized on the basis of 25 years and 5 percent interest.

    **/
    — The 1976 operating and maintenance figures were derived by applying the proportion of O&M costs

        to total capital in 1968 to the total 1976 capital.

-------
                         Footnotes
(1)    Bramer, H. C., The Economic Aspects of Water Pollution
      Abatement Program in the Ohio River Valley, " Doctoral
      Dissertation, University of Pittsburgh, I960.

(2)    Environmental Protection Agency, The Economics of Clean
      Water,  1972.
                             82

-------
                        SEC TION V

      ESTIMATING WATER QUALITY AS A FUNCTION

               OF POLLUTION CONTROL
       The methodology described herein is for estimating pollu-
tion costs as a function of water quality and abatement costs as a
function of degree of pollution control.  At first glance,  this may
appear to be  a trivial discrepancy in terminology.  Unfortunately,
that is not the case.  If for  example, BOD  levels in effluent were
reduced by 90 percent during the next five  years in a given basin,
the BOD level of the basin's surface water would probably not be
reduced by exactly 90 percent.  Water quality must be estimated
as a function of pollution control efforts before meaningful cost
comparisons can be made.

       Traditionally, the quality/control relationship has been
implicitly included in the benefit estimates or the  cost estimates.
An excellent  example of such a  methodology is provided by Matson
and Bennett in their study of the Maumee River Basin where both
benefits and costs are estimated as a function of degree of pollu-
tion control (1)  (see Exhibit V-l).  Although such a technique may
simplify computational requirements and yield comparable benefit
and cost curves, the shortcomings are far more significant.  The
physical relationships involved  in pollution control processes are
placed in a passive exogenous setting and benefit estimates become
dependent upon the accuracy of  quality/control estimates which
are hidden from view.  Benefit  estimates in such cases  can,  at
best,  be only as good as the quality/control estimates.  Also,
this approach requires  developing different benefit functions for
areas with different quality/control relationships even if the rele-
vant economic characteristics of the areas are identical.  In sum-
mary, such an approach may be acceptable for specific  problem or
crisis oriented studies  but does not exhibit the flexible character-
istics requisite for a national pollution control study.

       EPA has recognized the need for relating pollution loads
to water quality.  For example, in describing the  relationship
of their classification system for pollution sources and their
pollution index system, they  state:
                             83

-------
  o
  p
  M

  C

  O
  •r4

  3
  •t-l


  s
to  £
o  w
o  «
                            V    Annual Benefits
           30  -
           zo  -
            10
                                                                       100
                                BOD  REMOVAL (Percent)
 Exhibit V-l.
      Source:
Effect of degree of removal of dissolved organic

matter from effluents on annual costs and economic

benefits due to pollution abatement in the Maumee

River Basin.


Matson, Jack V.  and Bennett,  GaryF., "Cost of Industrial

and Municipal Waste Treatment in the Maumee River Basin, "


Water-1969,  Lawrence K. Cecil (ed.)» Chemical Engineering

Progress  Symposium Series,  Vol.  65,  No. 97, American

Institute of Chemical Engineers, New York, 1969.


                  84

-------
           The pollution source allocation is intended to produce
           a picture of the relative contributions of various acti-
           vities that are  pollution sources  (note that not all acti-
           vities or waste discharges necessarily result in pollu-
           tion, as defined) to the situation  reflected in the index.
           Precious efforts to establish such a ranking were hind-
           ered by a lack of correspondence of source contribu-
           tions with geographically unique  indicators of the re-
           sulting stream pollution and its effects.  In addition
           to offering progress to the  goal of associating dis-
           charges with pollution impacts,  the present approach
           provides a means of unambiguously aggregating measures
           of source contributions to meet higher level planning
           information needs.  (2)

       Recognizing the necessity for relating water quality to
pollution control levels on a national basis,  the literature was
searched for proven methodology.   The results of the search
pointed out a crying need for further study in this  research area
since published articles which treated the topic in anything more
than casual reference could not be found.  If further searches of
the literature were undertaken, the prospects of discovering sig-
nificant references appear dim.

        Since quality/control functions are a key determinant
 in the analysis set forth herein, and in view of the lack of
 acceptable documented approaches, we have undertaken the
 development of such a methodology.  Our suggested approach
 is summarized below, prefaced with general discussions on
 measuring water quality, determinants  of water quality and
 measuring the degree  of pollution control.
 A.   Measuring Water Quality

         Water quality is a nebulous term normally used in describing
 the abundance of pollutants in a sample of water or the suitability
 of a water source for a given use.  The former interpretation im-
 plies physical,  chemical and biological properties while the latter
 interpretation includes properties which are more appropriately
 termed esthetic qualities.

         Hence,  one can speak of physical water quality,  esthetic
 water quality or composite water quality where both physical

                               85

-------
and esthetic properties are combined.  Some commonly used
water quality  measurements are listed in Exhibit V-2.

        Given  a set of water quality measurements, a classification
problem exists in ranking the quality of surface waters.  One classi
fication system ranks water as  either potable  (i.e. , fit for human
consumption)  or non-potable.  This classification  system is  based
upon a set of physical,  chemical, and biological measures as illus-
trated in Exhibit V-3.  Since a large proportion of municipalities
in the U.S. pretreat their water supplies and large amounts  of
water are used for purposes other than human consumption,  pota-
bility isn't an adequate  classification system for this  study.
Another classification system is used to 'reflect the degree of-
hardness while still another is tied to the  degree of salinity
(Exhibit V-4).  Some studies have  ranked  water quality on the
basis of other singular  criterions such as dissolved oxygen and
biochemical oxygen demand.  Although these are of interest  they
are not  adequate for the current study.

        In 1968, the National Technical Advisory Committee on
 Water Quality Criteria set forth water quality recommendations
 for general use classifications  (3).  Their recommendations could,
 in most cases, be interpreted as guidelines for judging water as
 suitable or not suitable for a given use.   In some  instances,
 ranges  of acceptable quality measurements were  defined. Similar
 water quality guidelines have been formulated by  other agencies
 with California's  efforts probably being the most  notable example.

        In 1971, Prati, Pavanello and Pesarin presented a method
 for ranking water quality with an index number ranging from 1 to 8
 (5).   The criteria they proposed are presented,in Exhibit  V-5,  Un-
 fortunately, their system is based solely upon physical consider-
 ations .

        In January,  1972 Battelle's Columbus  Laboratories re-
 ported  the development of an environmental evaluation system
 for water resource planning (6).  Developed for the U.S. Bureau
 of Reclamation, the system ranks composite environmental qual-
 ity on a scale of 0 to 1000.  Components and associated weights
 for their  system are presented in Exhibit V-6.  The  system seems
 to be the  most comprehensive environmental quality  ranking scheme
 developed to date  and is currently being further refined in a contract
with the Arizona Department of Economic Planning and  Develop-
ment (7).

                             86

-------
Exhibit V-2.  Selected water quality characteristics
Physical Characteristics

Biochemical oxygen demand (BOD)
Dissolved oxygen (DO)
Chemical oxygen demand  (COD)
Fecal Coliform bacteria
Total dissolved solids (TDS)
Total suspended solids (TSS)
Hydrogen-ion concentration (pH)
Inorganic phosphate
Inorganic nitrogen
Inorganic carbon
Temperature
Hardness (as CaCOj)
Specific electric  conductance
Radioactivity
Toxic substances (including pesticides)
Turbidity
Color
Oil
Esthetic Characteristics

Taste
Appearance
Odor
Floating materials
Shoreline appearance
Biota
Man-made objects
Human interest
Source:   Dee, Norbert, et al., Environmental Evaluation System
          for Water Resource Planning, Battelle Columbus Laboratories
          for Bureau of Reclamation,  U. S. Department of the Interior,
          Washington, 1972.

          Chow, Ven Te (ed.)» Handbook of ^Applied Hydrology,  McGraw-
          Hill, New York, 1964.

          Todd, David Keith (ed.)» The Water Encyclopedia, Water
          Information Center,  Port Washington, N. Y.
                            87

-------
Exhibit V-3.  Drinking water standards of the U.S. Public Health
             Service, 1962.

 A.  General Constituents

                                 Recommended limits   Mandatory limits
      Substance                   of concentrations,      of concentrations
 	in mg/1	in mg/ 1	
 Alkyl benzene sulfonate (ABS)           0.5
 Arsenic (As)                            0.01                0.05
 Barium (Ba)                              --                 1.0
 Cadmium (Cd)                            --                 0.01
 Carbon chloroform extract (CCE)        0.2
 Chloride (C 1)                         250
 Chromium (hexavalent) (Cr+°)             --                 0.05
 Copper (Cu)                            1.0
 Cyanide (CN)                           0.01                0.2
 Fluoride (F)                              *                   *
 Iron  (Fe)                               0.3
 Lead (Pb)                                 --                 0.05
 Manganese  (Mn)                        0.05
 Nitrate (NOs)**                        45
 Phenols                                0.001
 Selenium (Se)                             --                 0.01
 Silver  (Ag)                                --                 0.05
 Sulfate (S04)                          250
 Total dissolved solids (TDS)           500
 Zinc  (Zn)	5	--
 *See  below
 **In areas in which the nitrate content of water is known to be in
   excess of the listed concentration, the public should be warned
   of the potential dangers of using the water for infant feeding.

 B. Fluoride
Annual average of maximu
daily air temperatures,
in degrees Fahrenheit
50.
53.
58.
63.
70.
79.
0 -
8 -
4 -
9 -
7 -
3 -
53.
58.
63.
70.
79.
90.
7
3
8
6
2
5
m Recommended control limits -
fluoride concentrations, inmg/1
Lower
0.
0.
0.
0.
0.
0.
9
8
8
7
7
6
Optimum
1.
1.
1.
0.
0.
0.
2
1
0
9
8
7
Upper
1.
1.
1.
1.
1.
0.
7
5
3
2
0
8
                             88

-------
Exhibit V-3 (continued)
C.   Radioactivity
            Source
   Recommended limits,
micromicrocuries per liter
         Radium -226
         Strontium - 90
         Gross beta activity
                3
               10
            1,000
Source:  Todd, David Keith (ed.), The Water Encyclopedia, Water
         Information Center,  Port Washington, N.  Y.
                              89

-------
Exhibit V-4. Classification of water quality according to hardness
             and salinity properties.

A.   Based on Concentration of Total Dissolved Solids
        Name
 Concentration of Total Dissolved Solids
	parts^ per million   	
        Fresh
        Brackish
        Salty
        Brine
                   0-1,000
               1,000-10,000
              10,000-100,000
          More than-100,000
 B.   Based on Hardness
        Name
      Hardness as CaCO^, Parts
        	per million
        Soft
        Moderately hard
        Hard
        Very hard
               0-60
               61-120
              121-180
        More than 180
Source:  Todd, David Keith (ed.)t The Water Encyclopedia.
         Water Information Center,  Port Washington, N.Y.

         Davis and DeWiert, Hydrogeology,  John Wiley and Sons, 1966.

         Anonymous, various publications of the U.  S. Geological
         Survey,  Washington.
                             90

-------
Exhibit V-5.  Assessment of surface water quality by a single index of pollution
Classification of
Condition:
Index of quality:
Quality Characteristic
PH
Dissolved oxygen
BOD (ppm)
COD (ppm)
Permanganate(mgl -0)
(Kubel test)
Suspended solids (ppm)
NH3 (ppm)
NO3 (ppm)
Cl (ppm)
Iron (ppm)
Manganese (ppm)
ABS (ppm)
CCE (ppm)
Excellent
1

6.5-8.0
88-112
1.5
10
2.5

20
0.1
4
50
0. 1
0.05
0.09
1.0
Acceptable
2

6.0-8.4
75-125
3.0
20
5.0

40
0.3
12
150
0.3
0. 17
1.0
2.0
Surface Water Quality
Slightly
Polluted
4

5.0-9.0
50-150
6.0
40
10.0

100
0.9
36
300
0.9
0.5
3.5
4.0
Polluted
8

3.9-10.1
20-200
12.0
80
20.0

278
2.7
108
620
2.7
1.0
8.5
8.0
Heavily
Polluted
> 8

<3.9-2 10. 1
<20->200
> 12.0
>80
> 20.0

>278
> 2.7
>108
>620
5 2.7
> 1.0
> 8.5
> 8.0
 Source:  Prati, L. , Pavanello, R.  and Pesarin, F. , "Assessment of Surface
         Water Quality by a Single Index of Pollution," Water Resources Research
         (GB), No.  5,  pp. 741-51,  1971.
                                       91

-------
Exhibit V-6.  Battelle's Environmental Evaluation System
                                                        Parameter
   Components                                      Importance Units
Ecology                                                  240

   Species and Population                                140
       Terrestrial
             Browsers and grazers                        14
             Crops                                        14
             Natural Vegetation                            14
            Pest species                                  14
             Upland game bird                             14

       Aquatic
             Commercial fisheries                         14
             Natural Vegetation                            14
            Pest species                                  14
             Sport fish                                    14
             Waterfowl                                    14

   Habitats and Communities                              100
       Terrestrial
             Food web index                                12
             Land use                                      12
            Rare and  endangered species                   12
            Species diversity                              14

       Aquatic
             Food web index                               12
             Rare and endangered species                  12
             River characteristics                         12
             Species diversity                            14

   Ecosystems
       Descriptive only
                                  92

-------
Exhibit V-6 (continued)
                                                      Parameter   #1
Components                                      Importance Units

Environmental Pollution                               402

     Water Pollution                                   318
        Basic hydrolic loss                            20
        BOD                                           25
        Dissolved Oxygen                              31
        Fecal coliforms                                18
        Inorganic carbon                               22
        Inorganic nigrogen                             25
        Inorganic phosphates                           28
        Pesticides                                     16
        pH                                            18
         Stream flow variation                         28
         Temperatures                                 28
         Total dissolved solids                         25
         Toxic substances                              14
         Turbidity                                     20

     Air Pollution                                      52
          Carbon monoxide                              5
          Hydrocarbons                                 5
          Nitrogen Oxides                              10
           Particulate matter                           12
           Photochemical  oxidants                       5
           Sulfur oxides                                10
           Other                                        5

     Land Pollution                                     28
           Land use                                    14
                                                       1
           Soil erosion                                 14

     Noise Pollution                                     4
           Noise                                        4
                               93

-------
Exhibit V-6 (continued)

                                                       Parameter   #1
 Components                                        Importance Units

 Esthetics                                             153

     Land                                              32
        Geologic surface material                        6
        Relief and topographic character                16
        Width and alignment                            10

     Air                                                 5
        Odor and visual                                 2
        Sounds                                          ^

     Water                                            52
        Appearance of water                           10
        Land and water interface                       1°
        Odors and  floating material                     "
        Water surface area                             10
        Wooded and geologic shoreline                  10

     Biota                                             24
        Animals -  domestic                             5
        Animals -  wild                                  5
        Diversity of vegetation types                    9
        Variety within vegetation types                   5

     Man-made objects                                 10
        Man-made objects                              10

     Composition                                      30
        Composite effect                               15
        Unique composition                             15
                                94

-------
Exhibit V-6 (continued)
                                                    Parameter  #1
Components                                      Importance Units
Human Interests                                      205
    Educational/Scientific Packages                    48
       Archeological                                  13
       Ecological                                     13
       Geological                                     H
       Hydro logical                                   H

    Historical Packages                               55
       Architecture and Styles                         H
       Events                                         H
       Persons                                        H
      Religious and Cultures                          H
       "Western Frontier"                            n

    Cultures                                          28
       Indians                                        14
       Other ethnic groups                             7
       Religious groups                                ^

    Mood/Atmosphere                                37
       Awe-inspiration                                H
       Isolation/solitude                              ^
       Mystery                                         4
       "Oneness" with nature                          H

    Life Patterns                                     37
        Employment Opportunities                     ^3
        Housing                                       13
        Social Interaction                             11
 *1  Total parameter importance units equals 1000.
 Source: Dee,  Norbert, et al. , Environmental Evaluation System for
         Water Resource  Planning, Battelle Columbus Laboratories for
          Bureau of Reclamation, U. S. Department of the Interior,
          Washington,  1972.
                               95

-------
       Another significant water quality classification methodo-
logy is the PDI (pollution prevalence, duration, intensity) system
being utilized by the Environmental Protection Agency (2). The
PDI has the distinct disadvantage of being tied to legal criteria.
If quality is such that damages are occurring to some beneficial
uses but legal criteria are being met, the water apparently is still
rated as high quality.  Furthermore,  the measurements upon which
the PDI are dependent (Exhibit V-7) are  rather arbitrary and may
prove difficult to apply consistently.  The relative weights given
to ecological, utilitarian and esthetic aspects of pollution could
be questioned.  Even though the  PDI has several undesirable
attributes, it is, perhaps, the most widely applied composite
water quality classification system.

       Currently, Federal,  state and local agencies are operating
thousands of water quality monitoring stations. Results from many
of these stations are recorded in the STORET data retrival system
maintained by the Environmental Protection Agency.  It is also
reported that the U.S. Geological Survey maintains  a large file
of water quality data.  An abundance of water quality data appears
to be available.  These data should be sufficient to meet the needs
of physical quality classification systems such as  the 8 point system
proposed  by Prati, Pavanello and Pesarin but generally fall short of
providing the requisite esthetic data for a system  such as the one
developed by Battelle.  EPA's PDI system is being applied on a
nation-wide basis and the results are available.
B.   Determinants  of Water Quality

       In examining the relationship between water quality and
pollution control levels, it is necessary to consider the physical
processes which determine quality of surface waters.  Of course,
one of the primary determinants of quality is the quantity and type
of pollutants entering the body of water. However,  of equal im-
portance is the inherent ability of  surface waters to naturally
purify themselves through their capacity to assimilate wastes.
                             96

-------
      Exhibit V-7.  Components of the PDI water quality
                   measurement  system.^/
                                                    Possible
 Component                                         value s

                        W                               /
 Prevalence of pollution—                              £/

 Duration of pollution                                0-1.0
      Consecutive days  ^91                           ^-4
      92 ^  consecutive  days  -  183                      0.6
      184 ^  consecutive days S  274                    0.8
      Consecutive days  ^ 275                           1.0

 Intensity of pollution                                0-1,0
      Ecological                                     0-0.5
      Utilitarian                                     0-0.3
      Esthetic                                        0-0.2
a/
—  PDI = (prevalence) (duration) (intensity)

                                  PDI
         pollution index  = 	•	•	
                           total stream miles

—  A pollution zone is defined as a surface water area not con-
   sistently in compliance with legal criteria for water quality.
—  Prevalence = length of pollution zone in miles.

 Source: Anonymous, The Economics of Clean Water, Vols. I and II,
         U.  S. Environmental Protection Agency, Washington,  1972.
                               97

-------
        The following discussion by Sheppard T. Powell is quoted
from Chow's hydrology handbook:

            The waste-assimilative capacity of surface waters
            is generally considered to be the amount of waste
            which will not cause water-quality deterioration be-
            yond the limits required for other beneficial uses of
            the supply.  Because oxygen-demanding wastes are
            most frequently encountered, this capacity is com-
            monly given in terms of the bio-chemical oxygen
            demand (BOD) of the waste.  Other wastes are very
            important in determining the assimilative  capacity,
            however, and BOD should not be assumed  the only
            criterion.

            The greatest single factor controlling the overall
            waste-assimilative capacity of surfaqe waters is
            the amount of dilution that is  provided.

            The primary factors controlling the BOD assimilative
            capacity are dilution, temperature, and the relative
            rates of biochemical deoxygenation and atmospheric
            reoxyge nation.  (8)

Typical assimilative capacities for various types of streams are
shown in Exhibit V.-8.

       Powell further notes that different kinds of surface water
bodies typically have different levels of assimilative capacity.
Usually, water quality in an impoundment will be better than
the average quality of the influent stream.   The mixing of fresh
water and sea water in estuaries present a large  array of unique
quality considerations.   J8)

       Sources of surface water pollutants may be classified as
meterologic, domestic,  industrial, and agricultural {9).   In addi-
tion, consumptive use increases the concentration of suspended
and dissolved solids.  The primary components in each of these
classifications are listed in Exhibit V-9.
                              98

-------
Exhibit V-8.
Total assimilative capacity of streams of different
orders.



Stream
order
1
2
3
4
5
6

7

8

9
10

Average
dis-
charge
tcfs*
0.6
2.8
14
65
310
1,500

7,000

33,000

160,000
700.000


Average
depth
(ft)


0.55
35
1.8
2.7

5

12

25
45


Average
velocity
(ft per sec)


1.2
1.6
1.8
2.0

2.5

3.0

4.0
5.0

Coefficient
of reaera-
tion
(day'1)


9.3
5.5
2.6
1.8

1.0

.37

1 .19
.10

Total
length of
streams
(miles)
1 ,570,000
810,000
420,000
220,000
1 1 6,000
61,000

30,000

14,000

6,200
1300
Total assimilative
capacity
(Tons per day per
unit deficiency
in dissolved oxygen)


16,300
19,000
20,000
30,000

31,000

21 ,000

18,000
9,400


U.S. rivers repre-
sentative
of each order




Pecos
Shenandoah,
Raritan.
Allegheny, Kansas,
Rio Grande.
Tennessee,
Wabash.
Columbia, Ohio
Mississippi
 Source: Todd, David Keith (ed.)i  The Water Encyclopedia,  Water
         Information Center, Port Washington,  N. Y.

         Anonymous,  various publications of the U. S. Geological
         Survey, Washington.
                            99

-------
      Exhibit V-9.  Sources of surface water pollutants
 Contributing factor
      Principal quality input to surface waters
 Meteorologic
Dissolved gases native to atmosphere
Soluble gases from man's industrial activities
Particulate matter from industrial stacks,  dust,
 and  radioactive particles
Material washed from surface of earth, e.g.:
 Organic matter such as leaves,  grass, and other
   vegetation in all stages of biodegradation
 Bacteria associated with surface debris
   (including intestinal organisms)
 Clay,  silt,  and other mineral particles
 Organic extractives from decaying vegetation
 Insecticide  and herbicide residues
 Domestic use
 Industrial use
Agricultural use
Undecomposed organic matter,  such as garbage
  ground to sewer,  grease, etc.
Partially degraded organic matter such as  raw-
  wastes from human bodies
Combination of above two after biode gradation
  to various degrees of sewage treatment
Bacteria (including pathogens) viruses,  worm eggs
Grit from soil washings,  eggshells,  ground bone,
Miscellaneous organic  solids, e.g.,  paper, rags,
  plastics,  and synthetic materials
Detergents

Biodegradable organic matter having a wide
  range of oxygen demand
Inorganic solids, mineral residues
Chemical residues ranging from simple acids
  and alkalies to those of highly complex molecular
  structure
Metal ions

Increased concentration of salts and  ions
Fertilizer  residues
Insecticide and herbicide residues
Silt and soil particles
Organic debris, e.g., crop residues
Source:  Todd, David Keith (ed.), The Water Encyclopedia, Water
         Information Center, Port Washington, N. Y.

         McGauhey, Engineering Management of Water Quality,
         McGraw-Hill, New York, 1968.

                            100

-------
       Another method of classifying pollutant sources divides
sources into natural and man-made. Each of these can be further
divided into point and non-point sources in reference to concen-
trated effluents like municipal sewage (point) as opposed to dis-
persed effluents such as runoff from agricultural lands (non-point).
Since the  relationship of such a classification system to the one
presented in Exhibit V-9 is obvious, a detailed enumeration of the
natural versus man-made system, is omitted for brevity.
C.   Measuring Water Pollution Control Levels
        As with water quality, various methods are utilized
 to describe degrees of pollution control.   One commonly used
 method is that of describing the general control technique being
 used.  Some  agencies,  such as the U.S. Census Bureau {10) typically
 report water pollution control as none, primary, secondary or
 tertiary.  Others are more specific and describe the actual physical
 configurations of the treatment systems being utilized.  Such a
 measuring system  has the shortcomings of not accounting for
 pretreatment of industrial wastes which are later treated in
 municipal sewage plants, not specifically stating the quality of
 the effluent and not reflecting the magnitude of effluent flows.

        A slightly better approach consists of specifying the pro-
 portion of specific  pollutants (e.g. , organics measured as BOD)
 which are removed from the effluent on a source by source basis.
 However, such methodology yields substantial aggregation problems
 due to differential  effluent loads by source.

        If one wishes to define degree of control as a percentage
 or proportion, the most tractable approach consists of stating
 the proportion of  each specific pollutant removed throughout the
 region being studied. Even this approach  has its problems since
 pollution control technology, industrial activity, etc. may vary
 substantially within the  study area.  Also, total pollutant inflow
 into surface waters can not be specified unless both raw effluent
 flows  and concentrations are known.

        Unfortunately, even specification of total quantity of pollu-
 tants  contained in the treated effluent does not solve all the problems.
 Distribution of tlie effluent is important in how  it affects water qual-
 ity and s-ome effluents may never reach surface waters. Also,
                               101

-------
 relating water quality to each kind of pollutant could generate
 massive computational requirements while a common denomin-
 ator for combining dissimilar pollutants  into one aggregate
 measure is not readily at hand.

        In summary,  it seems any conventional means  of measuring
 or classifying the degree of pollution control creates some methodo-
 logical problems.
 D.  Aggregation

        Measuring water quality or pollution control effectiveness
 at a given geographic point at a given point in time  is much simpler
 than relating the level of pollution control to water  quality on a
 national or even a regional basis.  Neither surface  water quality
 nor effluent quality is consistent over time. Water quality varies
 with a host of influencing factors including flow, temperature and
 differential effluent loads due to  seasonal variations in economic
 activity.  Likewise,  effluent quality from a given treatment plant
 may vary with throughput and a variety of operating conditions.
 To illustrate the variability in surface water quality,  the  reader is
 referred to Exhibit V-10 which states variations in  dissolved solids
 and sediment concentrations of major basins in the  arid and  semi-
 arid portions of the United States.  It is also noted that the effective-
 ness of most treatment systems is described in terms of probabilitie
 For example, a system might remove 90 percent of the  BOD load 90
 percent of the time.

       Hence, when  one speaks of relating benefits  to water  quality
 it is implicitly assumed that water quality is being reflected  as atx
 average measure.  The same is true for  relating costs to degree of
 control.  Recognizing that  surface water  and effluent quality  data
 are often available on a temporal sampling basis as opposed  to a
 continuous monitoring basis, such samples must be aggregated to
 yield a composite average annual quality measure.  The simplest
method of aggregating such data over time is to compute the  simple
average of the sample values.  If the samples are not uniformity
distributed through time, the samples may first be adjusted to reflect
relative time weights.  Alternatively, samples may be weighted  by
rate of flow to more accurately reflect total volume  of pollutant load
                           102

-------
Exhibit V-10.   Variations in Dissolved Solids and Sediment Concentrations
       in Major River Basins in Arid and Semiarid United States
          Region
                               Dissolved solids
                             concentrations, mg/1
                             From         To
                                                        Sediment concentrations,
                                                               mg/1-7	
From
                                                                         To
Columbia River Basin
Northern California
Southern California
Colorado River Basin
Rio Grande Basin
Pecos River Basin
Western Gulf of Mexico Basins
Red River Basin
Arkansas River Basin
Platte River
Upper Missouri River Basin
<100
^100

-------
EPA's PDI system utilizes still another approach for assessing
surface water quality with emphasis placed upon number of con-
secutive days that the water quality doesn't meet legal quality
criteria  (see Exhibit V-7).  A final approach might be to weight
the surface water quality samples by rate of  surface water utili-
zation for  beneficial uses.  Procedures utilized in published
sources  varies with no universally accepted technique apparent.
It is suggested that the technique  which is most appropriate depends
upon the end use of the data and the overall methodology employed
in the  study.  Recommendations for temporal quality aggregations
in reference to national analysis of pollution  control efforts are
presented  in the final section of this chapter.

       The geographic dispersion of water quality sampling stations
presents similar problems.  Water quality often varies substantially
along a given stream.  Typically,  quality of a stream tends to  in-
crease as  one moves from the mouth toward the source.  Although
some researchers indicate a  need for one aggregate national water
quality number, we  feel such a measurement would not be meaning-
ful in terms of a comparison  of national pollution costs and control
costs. Furthermore, such measurements for major basins seem
undesirable.  For example, the Missouri River is of very low
quality downstream  of Omaha.  However, some of the upper reaches
of the Missouri are  of much higher quality.  To average the quality
for the entire Missouri River Basin would seem to be an extreme
sacrifice of accuracy for computational expediency unless an ela-
borate aggregation methodology was  employed.  It seems more
reasonable to look at sub-basins or even zones within sub-basins
such that the geographic study area exhibits a fairly constant level
of water quality. Aggregation of water quality over sub-basins or
zones even poses methodology problems.

       As  with time considerations surface water quality data  may
be geographically aggregated by taking the simple geographic average
of average annual quality for  the sampling stations.  However, such
a simplistic approach ignores the distribution of beneficial uses
and sampling stations.  An approach like that utilized in the PDI
system resolves  the latter problem but doesn't adequately account
for the distribution of beneficial uses.  We feel the best approach
would be to assign a population base  to each sampling station and
then weight the samples on the basis of population.  However, we have
not been able to isolate studies utilizing this latter approach.   Even
                                104

-------
the population weighting scheme has the disadvantage of not cor-
rectly weighting water quality in low population areas with high
recreational or ecological value.  To reflect non-population
associated benefits, one could add a consideration for geographic
area represented into the weighting methodology.  Several other
variations  could also be proposed but, need  not be elaborated at
this point.

       Degree of control adds yet another dimension to the aggre-
gation problem.  Effluent discharges are not evenly distributed
throughout a given  study area and the effluent load generated within
an area has an impact upon the quality of surface waters in down-
stream areas. It must also be recognized that the type of treat-
ment and operational effectiveness of treatment processes will
vary by effluent source.  Data on  effluent quality is not as readily
available as surface water quality data but,  similar aggregation
techniques are applicable where data are available.
E.   Recommended Approach

        The purpose of this section is to recommend an approach
for relating degree of control to surface water quality within a
national water pollution control assessment framework.  The sug-
gested approach is in keeping with the short run, partial equilibrium
methodology outlined in Chapter II.  It is felt that data required for
the recommended approach is  consistent with long term planning
requirements.  However, it must be stressed that this approach
has been developed for short term planning purposes only and is
not an adequate methodology when viewed in terms  of general
equilibrium analysis which should be preferred in the  longer run.
Furthermore, the reflection of physical relationships  is cast in a
rather  subjective  setting since no rigorous approach is currently
available which could be applied on a national basis  given reasonable
time and budget constraints.

Specific Measurements

        For the purposes of this study the water quality characteristics
displayed in Exhibit V-ll have been adopted as measurements of water
quality. For current purposes, we do not foresee a need nor the utility
to aggregate all characteristics into a composite index.  This does not,
                             105

-------
however, mean that we suggest further work with composite in-
dices should be abondoned.  Indices such as the PDI can play a
very important role in water quality monitoring and other re-
search areas and should be further pursued.  Even though some
esthetic measures are included in the list,  it is recognized that
in many cases  such data are not readily available.  For a further
discussion of specific measurements, the reader is referred to
Appendix A of this report.
Water Quality Assumptions

       If the analytical procedures adopted for assessing national
pollution control efforts are to be tractable, a number of water
quality assjmptions are necessary.  For brevity, the assumptions
adopted herein are listed below in list form.

       1.  Average levels of water quality within a geographic
           area are adequate for current purposes--!, e. ,  daily
           quality variations will be ignored.

       2.  The quality for any given surface water body at 100
           percent point pollution control can be estimated.

       3.  The quality for any given surface water body at 100
           percent control of all man-made pollutants (i. e. ,
           point and non-point) can be estimated.

       4.  The quality impacts of natural pollution will be  taken
           as an exogenous factor.

       5.  The cyclic impact of water pollution  control upon
           air quality which, in turn, affects the quality of
           meterologic water and then surface waters will be
           ignored.

       6.  Current water quality and water quality at  100 percent
           point and point plus non-point pollution control can be
           taken as three points on the same curve and the shape
           of that curve can be subjectively derived for any given
           surface water body.
                             106

-------
Exhibit V-ll.  Water quality characteristics adopted for this study
Physical Characteristics                 E s the tic C ha rac te r i s tic s

Biochemical oxygen demand              Floating solids
Chemical oxygen demand                 Taste
Fecal coliform bacteria                 Odor
Total dissolved solids                   Biota
Total suspended solids                   Appearance —
Hydro gen-ion concentration (pH)
Inorganic phosphate
Inorganic nitrogen                   ^ .
Toxic substances and trace elements —
Hardness (as CaCO3)
Temperature
Radioactivity
Color
Turbidity
Oil
*/
—  As used here, appearance is a composite measure including color,
   turbidity, rate of flow, shoreline appearance, etc.
**/
— Includes heavy metals
                              107

-------
  Water Pollution Control Assumptions

         As with water quality,  assumptions concerning water pollution
  control levels are also necessary.  They are as follows:

          1.   Current levels of pollution control in any given area
              can be  generalized to a specific strategy.

         2.   Both non-point and point pollution are critical but com-
              prehensive data for the former will limit its analysis.

         3.   Seasonal variations in effluent flow and quality will
              be  included to the extent available but it is anticipated
              that annual averages will be used in most cases due to
              data limitations.

  Re la ting Quality to Abatement

         The general form of the surface water quality level of abate-
  ment relationship is as depicted in Exhibit V-12.  One such relation-
  ship is required for each pollutant or water quality measurement in
  each sub-basin or pollution zone.  It is noted that the relationships
  for  one specific water quality characteristic is not  necessarily inde-
  pendent of other water quality  characteristics.  Care must be taken
  to adequately reflect these synergistic  relationships even if it re-
  quires a separate set of quality abatement curves for each abatement
  strategy to be considered.  To the furtherest extent possible, such.
  curves should also  be developed for seasons of the  year.
       Recognizing that surface water quality within a geographic
study area may not be uniform, the problem of weighting samples
from monitoring stations must be considered.  Furthermore, it
must be noted that economic activity, biota, senic attractions,  etc.
are not apt to be uniformily distributed.  Hence,  an average water
quality number designed to most accurately reflect quality for one
beneficial use may not be the most appropriate for another beneficial
use.
                            108

-------
to
.-J
fc
fl>
*J
O
«J
M
O
 >>
 Vi
 I
 ri
 O
 .
 i
 o
                     Pollutant load
                                       Degree of control

    Exhibit V-12.  General form of surface water quality - degree of
                  control curves.
                                 109

-------
        One could generate an average surface water quality number
for each beneficial use category in the study area.  However,  such
an undertaking on a national basis seems unreasonable. Another
possibility is to generate two quality numbers:  one weighted by
population and one by geographic area.   But,  if study areas  are
carefully chosen, the population weighted number may  not be signi-
ficantly different from the area weighted number.  If the latter possi-
bility proves true when actual data are examined, the geographic
weighting technique is  recommended since it eases computational
requirements.  It is hoped that further examinations will show that
average area of surface water between monitoring stations can serve
as a surrogate for geographic area.

        Distribution of effluents is as important as water quality  samples,
One approach would be to assume all effluents entered  the surface
water system at its centroid.  Another would be to evenly distribute
it with  respect to geographic area.  However, we recommend  a more
difficult approach which entails estimating the proportion of total
effluents entering the surface water  system between monitoring
stations.  The latter approach seems warranted since it properly
accounts for large effluent concentrations which may occur near a
study area boundary.

        Given appropriate measurements of surface water and  effluent
quality, the impact of a given abatement strategy  must  be  traced
throughout the length of a basin, starting at the uppermost reach and
progressing toward the lower end  of the basin.

        To illustrate and clarify the procedures  discussed above, a
simple example is given below.
F.   An Illustrated Example

       When describing a methodology, it is sometimes beneficial to
illustate its application.  Such an approach is taken in this final section
describing the  relationship of degree of pollution control and water
quality.  Even  though an hypothetical example would have sufficed,
it was felt a real world example would be more meaningful.  In the
following example, we have combined some hypothetical and subjective
elements with, hopefully, enough actual data to yield a meaningful
illustration.
                              110

-------
       Municipal and industrial effluent data representative of the
Maumee Sub-basin of the Lake Erie Basin were adapted from Matson
(11).  Water quality data for one year at the mouth of the same sub-
basin were adapted from the U.S. Public Health Service ( !2).  The
data was subjectively modified to adjust for what seemed to be
unusual circumstances.  In an actual study, examination of more
than one year's water quality data would be required but,  such an
undertaking would have further delayed preparation of this report
and, hence, seemed unwarranted for the current illustrative example.
The same argument is true for a subjective modification required to
place effluent flows and water quality data in the same time frame.
Hence,  the data should be viewed as hypothetical rather than being
truly reflective of the Maumee Sub-basin.

        The illustrative sub-basin displays  average monthly temper-
atures ranging from the  20's in January to  the 70"s in July. Annual
precipitation varies from 28 to 40 inches with the average being
about 35 inches.  The surface waters  have  high levels of dissolved
phosphate and hardness.  Plankton flora are abundant and diverse.
The sub-basin is roughly circular with a fifty-mile radius en-
compassing roughly 6, 500 square miles.  Total stream miles  are
about 2,800 which includes  nearly 300 streams.  Land in the sub-
basin is very flat with natural conditions without drainage, being
predominately heavily wooded marshlands.  The soils are fine
textured, poorly drained and  relatively impermeable. The 1968
population of 1.2 million was centered around Toledo, Lima and  Fort
Wayne.  Industrial activity includes primary and fabricated metals,
oil refining, glass,  chemicals, machinery, meatpacking, brewing
and other food processing.  Agricultural activity is highly developed
with predominant enterprises including vineyards and orchards.   The
sub-basin includes a number of recreational developments ( Hi  12).

        Raw and treated  effluent flows for the illustrative  case appear
in Exhibit V-13.  Nonpoint  effluents after treatment were assumed to
equal 25 percent of total treated effluents.  Both point and nonpoint
flows were assumed to be equally distributed throughout the year.
Only the BOD load is presented with the implication that other
effluent and water quality factors would be handled in the  same
manne r.
                               Ill

-------
Exhibit V-13.  Raw and treated effluent flows, illustrative case
                                       BOD in 1000 Ibs/day
Pollutant source                 raw—           after treatment
Point sources
Municipalities
Industrial
Total
Nonpoint sources
Total

201
266
467
N.A.
N.A.

36
31
67
22
89
*/
—  N.A. denotes not available
   Source:  Point flows adapted from Matson, Jack V. , Cost of
            Industrial and Municipal Water Pollution Abatement
            in the Maumee River Basin, unpublished Master's
            Thesis, University of Toledo,  1968.

            Nonpoint flows are hypothetical estimates.
                                  112

-------
       Water quality at the mouth of the basin varies substantially during
the year.  BOD levels vary from less than 0.5 to nearly 18 milligrams per
liter.  Weighting BOD levels in each sample by the period of time between
samples yields average levels  in milligrams per liter as  follows:  January-
March 8.6,  April-June 4.8, July-September 3.5, October-December 7.7.
Again, note that these data include subjective adjustments as described
above.

       By examining conditions of the sub-basin,  conditions and water
quality data in other areas in the basin and surrounding areas and applying
general water quality principals, two more sets of water quality points
were estimated:  one for  100 percent reduction of point pollution and
one for 100  percent reduction of point pollution plus elimination of all
non-point man-made pollution.  The latter point corresponds to what
water quality in the basin would be under natural conditions given cur-
rent vegetative patterns.   These points are presented in Exhibit  V-14.

       Given the water quality for 1968 conditions,  100 percent point
control and  100 percent point and nonpoint control and given effluents
for each level of quality,  the relationship  of pollution level to water
quality can be graphed as shown in Exhibit V-14 .  The curves for the
second and fourth quarters of the year do  not correspond to what one
would anticipate.  It is suggested that this is a  result of the assumption
that nonpoint pollution is evenly distributed throughout the year.  Even
this simple  case points out the inseparability of point and nonpoint pollu-
tion in terms of quality impacts.  If one were to assume nonpoint pollu-
tion was more heavily concentrated in spring and early summer and less
heavily concentrated in the remainder of the year, all four curves  would
display the  same basic shape.

        Two  significant conclusions can be drawn from the relationships
depicted in  Exhibit V-14.  First, water quality varies over time  and hence
the impact of a pollution abatement strategy will vary over time.   There-
fore, the  benefits accruing from a given strategy will vary over time and
the total benefit calculated on an average  annual basis may not be the
same total benefits calculated on an average quarterly basis (note:
benefits are not normally a linear function of quality).  Second, the
level of nonpoint pollution will partially determine Both the magnitude
and slope of the quality/pollution curve.  Hence, one cannot estimate
benefits from a given strategy unless something is known or at least
assumed  about the level and temporal distribution of non-point pollu-
tion.  Acceptance  of this latter conclusion places almost all previously
published benefit studies in a questionable light.
                               113

-------
        One further step is required to allow comparisons of benefits
and costs:  relating degree of pollution control to total effluent load.
That  relationship is depicted in Exhibit V-15.  The vertical intercept
is the total raw wasteload from point sources.  The dashed line cor-
responds to an 85 percent reduction in effluent BOD--i. e. , an after
treatment load of 67, 000 pounds per day as shown in Exhibit V-13.
Note  that degree of control is stated in terms of point pollution only.
This  approach is taken to provide consistency with data generally
found in the literature.  However, if so desired, one could easily
relate total effluent load to average degree of treatment for all
pollution sources including both point and non-point.

        Now given Exhibits V-14 and V-15, benefits and costs
could be meaningfully compared as described in the preceding
chapters  of this report.

        Before concluding this chapter,  one further comment seems
pertinent: the relationships depicted in Exhibit V-14 tend to be
dynamic while those depicted in Exhibit V-15 are static.   With in-
creasing levels of population and economic activity, the vertical
intercepts of the latter functions become higher and higher. In
other words,  it requires  a higher degree  of treatment to maintain
the same level of water quality.  Alternatively, gaines in treat-
ment  efficiency may be equally offset by increases  in the total raw
wastewater flow.  Hence  one can correctly conclude that if water
quality  remains constant over time and economic activity increases, ,
total benefits  will increase and cost of control per capita will in-
crease.  If per capita pollution costs remain constant while per capita
costs of control increase, this conclusion is  highly significant since the
economic justification for truly high quality water would diminish over
time.  We feel, however,  that technological advances  in the waste
treatment industry may well offset this effect, at least in the  short
run.  Also, when so called benefits from  pollution control are
viewed  in the  more appropriate framework of costs of pollution,
it may be possible to demonstrate that per capita costs of pollution
increases as the economy and populus expands.
                               114

-------
mg.  BOD5/1
in surface water
at mouth of  basin
               10   20    30    40   50    60    70   80    90   100
               1,000 Ibs BOD^/day in effluent entering surface waters

     Exhibit V-14. Surface water quality as a function of effluent load, BOD
                  by quarter of year, illustrative example.

                 I     - January -March
                 II    = April - June
                 III    = July - September
                 IV    = October - December

                                  115

-------
1,000 Ibs.
BOD/day from
point sources
 500


 450


 400


 350


 300


 250


 ZOO


 150


 100


  50
Raw Wasteload
            10    20    30   40    50   60    70

            % reduction in point source BOD load
                                        80    90
100
    Exhibit V-15. BOD content o£ treated effluent as a function of degree
                  of treatment, illustrative case.
                               116

-------
                        Footnotes
 (1)  Matson, Jack V. and Bennett,  Gary F., "Cost of Industrial
     and Municipal Waste Treatment in the Maumee River Basin,"
     Water-1969, Lawrence K. Cecil (ed.)» Chemical Engineering
     Progress Symposium Series, Vol. 65, No. 97,  American
     Institute of Chemical Engineers, New York, 1969.

 (2)  Anonymous, The Economics of Clean Water,  Vols. I and II, U.S.
     Environmental Protection Agency, Washington,  1972.

 (3)  Anonymous, Water  Quality Criteria, National Technical Ad-
     visory Committee on Water Duality Criteria, Federal Water
     Pollution Control Administration,  U.S. Department of the
     Interior, Washington, 1968.

 (4)  Anonymous, Water  Quality Criteria, California  State Water
     Quality Control Board, 1963.

 (5)  Prati, L. , Pavanello, R. and  Pesarin, F. , "Assessment of
     Surface Water Quality by a Single Index of Pollution," Water
     Re sources Research (GB), No. 5, pp. 741-51,  1971,

 (6)  Dee,  Norbert, et al., Environmental Evaluation System for
     Water Resource Planning, Battelle Columbus Laboratories for
     Bureau of Reclamation, U. S.  Department of the Interior,
     Washington, 1972.

 (7)  Plumlee,  Harry J., Arizona Department  of Economic  Planning
     and Development, personal discussions,  December, 1972.

 (8)  Chow, Ven Te (ed.), Handbook of Applied Hydrology, McGraw-
     Hill,  New York, 1964.

 (9)  Todd, David Keith (ed.),  The  Water Encyclopedia, Water
     Information Center, Port Washington, N. Y.

(10)  Anonymous, various publications concerning the 1970 Census,
     U.  S. Bureau of Census,  Washington.

(11)  Matson, Jack V. , Cost of Industrial and Municipal Water
     Pollution Abatement in the Maumee River Basin, unpublished
     Master's thesis, University of Toledo, 1968.

                               117

-------
(12)  Anonymous,  various water quality records published by the
     U. S. Public Health Service, Washington.

(13)  McGauhey, Engineering Management of Water Quality,
     McGraw-Hill, New York,  1968.

(14)  Davis and DeWient, Hydrology, John Wiley and Sons,  1966.

(15)  Anonymous,  various publications of the U. S. Geological
     Survey, Washington.
                               118

-------
                        SEC TION VI

    CONCLUSIONS AND DIRECTION OF FUTURE WORK
       The preceding chapters have gone considerably beyond a
simple enumeration of research needs and priorities.  This was
not a calculated extension but rather was the inevitable byproduct
of preliminary attempts to establish research needs and priorities
in an area of endeavor that is relatively unexplored and besieged
with controversy.  Many have studied the water quality problem but
very few have had the courage or found it necessary to venture out
of the protective shelter provided by the convenient simplifying
assumptions  amenable to and associated with estimating isolated
water quality impacts or even comprehensive impacts for a small
geographical area.  By changing the scope of the problem from
selected water quality impacts to comprehensive national impacts
the problem is transformed into a very circuitous  task that seems
to collapse at every point and thereby becomes almost totally defiant
of solution.   In this regard economics as a profession has not assisted
the policy-maker in his need for acquiring immediate answers  so as
to successfully allocate limited time, effort and resources to these
areas representing the greatest current need.  It is felt that the
expanded scope of this part of the project has been a valuable ex-
penditure of time in that many firm conclusions have been reached.
These include hypothesized results that might be expected from
extending previously conducted studies to derive national benefit
cost estimates, subjective judgments of areas of emphasis and re-
search needs,  and possible results of further research.  It is there-
fore fitting that as  a concluding note some of the salient points are
briefly summarized.  These items are briefly enumerated and dis-
cussed under several categories: methodological  conclusions , benefit
cost estimation and state-of-the-arts.  It further behooves us to
present these conclusions  in the most summarized and straightforward
manner possible.

A.  Methodological Conclusions

       It is indeed unfortunate that many of the methodological limi-
tations have  not been satisfied prior to this point in time.  In general,
the conclusions in  reference to methodology are as follows:

        1.   General equilibrium models, preferred on a theoretical
           basis,  are not currently implementable.  Sizeable  data
           problems, and lack of sufficient sensitivity to natural,
           physical and socioeconomic considerations prevent the
                              119

-------
            general equilibrium approaches from being utilized
            to ascertain immediate answers or estimates of
            water quality associated impacts.   There is a general
            lack of readily accessible methodology applicable to the
            water quality management problems.

       2.   Partial equilibrium models are not free of limitations
            but must be utilized in the short run.

       3.   Cost minimization's the preferred partial equilibrium
            approach in that it formulates the problem in its  proper
            conceptual framework.

       4.   Other deficiencies or limitations such as  the substitution
            phenomenon,  current aggregation problems and the trans•
            formation function relating degree of treatment and "re"^
            suiting surface water quality, prevent and prohibit ascer-
            taining socially optimum results.

       The  above items constitute the major methodological issues
that have been encountered.   These have been  recognized in the pre-
ceding chapters and in some cases steps were initiated to partially
eliminate the problems or at least to describe in more  detail the
considerations  that are involved.

B.  Benefit and Cost Estimation Conclusions
       1.  Pollution abatement cost estimates do not represent a
           pressing research need.

       2.  Water quality associated benefit estimation represents
           a pressing research need.

       3.  Benefit estimation methodology is currently lacking,
           especially in reference to intangible esthetic, recre-
           ation and ecological impacts.

       4.  Results  of existing studies can not be accurately extra-
           polated to derive national benefit (cost reduction) estimates

       5.  Pollution abatement standards do not appear justifiable
           basecl solely on monetary cost reductions.   Other indirect
           and intangible costs need to be quantified.
                             120

-------
       6.   The feasibility of national pollution abatement measures
           hinge almost entirely on recreation,  esthetic and eco-
           logical cost reductions. It is felt that these beneficial
           uses are the source of  sizeable benefit estimates or
           cost reductions and have not as of this time been ade-
           quately estimated primarily because of lack of appro -
           priate methodology.

       7.   Given current benefit estimation techniques national
           benefits  (cost reductions) jare not expected to be of
           sufficient magnitude to justify pollution abatement
           expenditures (annualized  costs).
       8
       8.   The  subjective benefit and cost material presented in
           Appendix A represents a  first effort to establish a
           national priority with respect to beneficial use and
           specific  pollutant and is viewed as possessing con-
           siderable value as  a planning and decision tool.

       The above items indicate that there are numerous short-
comings in benefit cost methodology and current estimates.  This
limitation stems primarily that previous work has been project-
problem-crisis oriented.  Few have attempted to identify and quan-
tify national impacts of water quality improvement in methods  other
than extrapolating existing studies.  This has  left sizeable metho-
dology and estimate voids, i.e. , for example, even though a great
deal is known about  the harmful effects of specific pollutants, no-
where have we been able to find listings of specific pollutants ac-
cording to the damage they inflict on a national basis.  The problem-
project-crisis approach leaves much to be desired in that national
directions  are left unspecified and are difficult to determine.  One
should not be  overly pessimistic in that the recognition of the problem
is the first step in the eventual solution. If Phase III could further
refine the direction of future study or make even very minor inroads
into the development of ecological, esthetic or recreational estima-
tion research needs and procedures, the contributions of the project
would be highly significant.

       Before suggesting  areas of emphasis for future research, it is
perhaps again instinctive to place  the problem in perspective by re-
focusing on the short-run  and  immediate research needs  listed in
Section I.   These short-run and immediate research needs and
priorities are reproduced below:
                              121

-------
C.  Short-Run Economic Research Needs and Priorities

       The following items constitute economic research needs
that could be at least partially satisfied in the short-run given
existing data and methodology constraints.   The three major
divisions and subdivisions are listed in their relative order of
importance.

       It should not be surprising to find that benefit estimation
is the singularly most important need to be  satisfied in the short-
run.

       I.   Develop, refine and implement methodology for
           assessing water quality associated  impacts with
           special emphasis  on the following short-run re-
           search needs.

           A.  Benefit estimation
               1.   Refinement of overall benefit estimation
                    methodology
               2.   Refinement and implementation of intangible
                    benefit estimation methodology and techniques
               3.   Estimation of substitution  impacts
               4.   Development of multivariate water quality
                    associated benefit functions
               5.   Interfacing economic,  hydrologic, biological
                    and engineering water quality models
               6.   Estimation of irreversible damages
               7.   Development of a satisfactory aggregation
                    scheme.

           B.  Cost estimation
               1.   Refinement of overall cost of pollution abate-
                    ment methodology
               2.   Development of nonpoint pollution estimate
                    and cost  of treatment
               3.   Development of a treatment versus resulting
                    stream quality function
               4.   Further development of least cost treatment
                    strategies
               5.   Development of cost aggregation framework
                               122

-------
           C.  Implicit in all of the above items is the development
               of a satisfactory data base including but not limited to
               the following items.
                1.   Pollutant level  by receptor
               2.   Effluent flows by source
               3.   Effluent flows by process
               4.   Precise water  quality monitoring data
               5.   Damage thresholds and impact ranges
               6.   C ritical effluent levels
               7.   Synergistic effects

      II.   Develop pollution abatement policy alternatives with
           special emphasis on the following items:

           A.  Development of spatially variable policies and
               abatement standards
           B.  Minimization of equity and distribution effects
           C.  Development of alternative policies to provide
               internal incentives  to reduce effluent loads

      III.   Analysis and inauguration of institutional and structural
           changes required to implement many of the above items.
D.   Immediate Research Needs and Priorities

       While all of the above items constitute short-run economic
research needs and priorities that could be eliminated  given present
data and methodology constraints, there is  great disparity in the
importance or urgency associated with each of these items.   There
is also the need to further develop and refine techniques useful in
appraising short-run priorities so as to  insure that current  resources
and efforts are properly directed.  For this reason those  items repre-
senting the  greatest need have been singled out and listed  below:
                             123

-------
        1.   Continue to develop, refine and implement procedures
            useful in ascertaining the most detrimental pollutants.
        2.   Continued refinement of water quality associated benefit
            estimation methodology.
        3.   Development and implementation of benefit estimation
            methodology appropriate for  the estimation of intangible
            water quality associated benefits.
        4.   Investigation of complex water quality substitution effects.
        5.   Development and implementation of multivariant benefit
            function (relating benefits to  several  key pollutants).
        6.   Interfacing economic, biological, hydrological and
            engineering models.

        The areas recommended for immediate emphasis should be
consistent with the areas representing the  greatest current needs.
The following items are therefore proposed possible areas  of im-
mediate emphasis and are consistent with the original areas of need.

       I.    Further development of general methodology applicable
            to assessing the impacts of water quality deterioration.
            Items of special interest may include attempts to explore
            selected methodological problems that are currently
            lacking and prohibit accurate water quality assessment.

            a.   Substitution effects
            b.   Treatment versus quality transformation functions
            c.   Aggregation schemes

      II.    Additional refinement of benefit matrix material pre-
            sented in Appendix A, with the expressed intent of achievinc
            refined, final priority ranking to be used as a decision tool
            and  general aid in providing direction for future research
            so that current efforts can be directed to those  areas
            representing the greatest current need.

      III.    In that the justification of future pollution abatement in-
            vestment seems to hinge on identification and quantification
            of ecological,  esthetic and recreational  impacts,  any effort
            expended in this direction has a great potential  value.   The
            third alternative is  therefore to devote time and effort to
            contribute to the development and refinement of associated
            methodological and  estimation problems.
                           124

-------
                        SECTION VII

                       APPENDICES
                                                             Page

A.    Appraisal of Costs of Control and Benefit Estimates       126

B.    Water Quality Associated Health Impacts                  160

C.    Specific Pollutants                                       175

D.    Critical Levels and Damage Thresholds                   185
                             125

-------
                         APPENDIX A

       Appraisal of Costs of Control and Benefit Estimates

                       State -of-the -Data
                              and
                      Subjective Estimates
       One of the purposes of this Phase II report is to provide an
insight into the current state-of-the-data with respect to costs of
water pollution control and the pollution cost reductions (benefits)
accruing therefrom.  Also,  this report is to address and provide
subjective estimates of costs of control, relative  magnitude of
beneficial uses, and relative importance of specific pollutants.
This appendix is dedicated to fulfilling these objectives.

Costs of Control - Introduction
       In examining costs of abatement, the following items are
relevant:

       1.   Total wastewater flow
       2.   Quality of untreated wastewater
       3.   Total wasteload before treatment
       4.   Treatment strategies employed
       5.   Proportion of wastewater that is treated
       6.   Quality of effluent after treatment
       7.   Total wasteload after treatment
       8.   Regional distribution of wasteflows

Each of these needs to be examined for each source group.
Furthermore,  it must be recognized that each item changes over
time and, hence, the dynamic characteristics of the problem
should be addressed.  This latter point is especially critical in
view of the current and anticipated rates of technological advance-
ment in the water pollution control industry.  Rates of change  in
population and economic  activity  are likewise important.  Also,
when interpreting abatement cost estimates, it should be recog-
nized that enforcement of effluent standards may, in the long run,
induce emitors to initiate structural changes resulting in reduced
                            126

-------
wasteflow or increased quality of raw effluent.  In short, any ob-
jective data currently available are the result of partial analyses
and must be regarded accordingly.  With these  qualifications in
mind, objective data  concerning the ten points listed above are
presented below for estimated conditions in 1968 and 1976.  Then,
meaningful data and benefit estimations can be pursued.

       The Environmental Protection Agency has divided pollution
sources into seven major categories (1):

       1.  Municipal
       2.  Industrial and power plants
       3.  Federal installations
       4.  Agricultural and rural
       5.  Mining
       6.   Water resource development
       7.   Transportation.

       Industrial sources have further been classified in accordance
with SIC (standard industrial code) numbers. In discussing costs  of
abatement below, EPA's  source classifications are utilized. How-
ever, wastewater flows and cost data are only presented for the first
two categories due to the state-of-the-arts of the data and  time con-
straints.

       Before further pursuing cost and benefit estimates, the
reader is forewarned that the data contained in this appendix were
assembled on a best  efforts basis.  They are presented here not be-
cause we feel they are  final answers nor, in some cases,  even good
estimates but, rather,  because of an acute awareness of the need for
such data on the part of the policy-makers involved in environmental
protection decision-making processes.   The tasks undertaken and
summarized herein were substantial and, in many cases,  unprece-
dented.  In view of the  awesome nature of the problem addressed,
both monetary considerations and length of time devoted to the under-
taking were far less  than what would be required to provide answers
with which we would  feel comfortable. However,  if the reader re-
minds himself of the potential pitfalls involved in deriving subjective
estimates  based upon very limited data and doing so in a very  short
time frame, we  feel  the results can be of highly significant value.
To our knowledge, the  rankings of both beneficial uses and pollutants
                              127

-------
by relative importance represent the first of their kind.  We feel they
represent a monumental first step toward establishing a water quality
research program soundly based upon anticipated results rather than
emotion or chaos.

Total Flows, Raw Effluent Quality and Total Wasteload^

       Estimated total wastewater flows by source group during
1968 are presented in Exhibit A-l.  Industrial wastewater flows are
for process water only. The exhibit also contains estimated total
wasteload by major pollutant based upon the concentrations which are
also shown.  It is immediately obvious that wastewater flows vary
substantially between source groups, suggesting that some source
groups such as chemicals and allied products and primary metals
may be far more significant from an environmental viewpoint than
others such as electrical machinery, rubber and plastics and textile
products.   Total wasteloads of specific pollutants are also unevenly
distributed between the source groups.

       Exhibit A-l should be viewed as incomplete in that several spe-
cifio pollutants which may be of interest are not reported and data are
not available in some instances for even the more  commonly studied
pollutants.  Expansion of these tables to include all effluent  quality
characteristics adopted in Chapter V of this report should be considered
as a priority area for further research.   It should also be noted that
the numbers reported in the tables  are estimates and, in some cases
the validity of the estimates are at best questionable.  Refining these
estimates for 1976 conditions should be viewed as  another research
priority area.

Treatment and Effluent Quality

       Since effluent characteristics vary by source group and even bv
process within a source group, different pollution abatement strate-
gies are required by source  group.   For current purposes,  the follow-
ing treatment strategies are considered (1):
                            128

-------
Exhibit A- 1.  Raw wasteflows and pollutant loads by source group,  1968
Food & kindred Textile mill
Item products products
Volumetric flow
(billion gallons/year)
Concentration before treatment
BOD (mg.//)
Total load (million Iba/yr)
COD (mg. IS. )
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
Fecal coliform bacteria
(106MPN/100 ml)
M Total dissolved solids(mg. iJi}
-° Total load (million Ibs/yr)
TSS
-------
Exhibit A- 1.   Raw wasteflows and pollutant loads by source group, 1968 (continued)
Petroleum
Item & coal
Volumetric flytf
(billion gallons/year)
Concentration before treatment
BOD (mg./l)
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
COD (mg./^)
Total load {million Ibs/yr)
^ Fecal coliform bacteria
Total dissolved solids (mg./J)
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
PH
Toxic substances (mg. /J! )
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
430
45
161
200
717
0
NA
42
150
4.5
NA
NA
Rubber &
plastics
62
30
15.4
60
30.8
0
0
0
37
19
NA
NA
NA
Leather
51
2,500
1, 070
3.000
1,290
0
30,000
12,800
2, 000
854
NA
NA
NA
Stone, clay
& glass
240
NA
NA
NA
NA
0
NA
NA
NA
NA
NA
NA
Primary
metals
1,820
15
228
80
1,214
0
NA
NA
130
1,970
NA
NA
NA
Fabricated metal
products
110
NA
NA
NA
NA
0
NA
NA
NA
NA
NA
NA
                                                        continued	

-------
                Exhibit A- 1.   Raw wasteflows and pollutant loads by source group, 1968 (continued)
Item
Volumetric flow
(billion gallons/year)
Machinery
99
Electrical
equipment
139
Transportation
equipment
160
Municipal
Wastewater
Industry not
Domestic reported elsewhere
6,142
411
Concentration before treatment
BOD (mg./ )
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
COD (mg./ )
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
»— Fecal coliform bacteria
£ (106MPN/100 ml)
Total dissolved solids(mg.
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
TSS (mg./ )
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
PH
Toxic substances (mg. / )
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
Source: Volumetric flow:
48
40
NA
NA
0
/ ) NA
NA
40
33
NA
NA
NA
92
107
NA
NA
-
NA
NA
26
30
NA
NA
NA
Environmental Protection Agency,
60
80
NA
NA
-
NA
NA
NA
NA
NA
NA
NA
The Economics of
276
14,137
350
17,930
200
700
35,800
200
10,250
NA
NA
NA
Clean Water, Vols.
276
946
350
1,200
200
700
2,400
200
685


I and II,
Other data:  DPRA subjective estimates.

-------
        1.   Oil separation
        2.   Equalization
        3.   Coagulation and sedimentation
        4.   Neutralization
        5.   Floatation
        6.   Sedimentation
        7.   Aeration
        8.   Biological stabilization
        9.   Chlorination
       10.   Evaporation
       11.   Incineration
       12.   Activated sludge

By taking a combination of these treatment processes,  one can
generally describe the treatment strategy of a given source group.
Exhibit A-2 represents such an undertaking. It is stressed that the
strategies so depicted are generalized and may  not be truly repre-
sentative of each and every emitor within a given source group.

Historically, a large proportion of the total waste flow was not
treated. Even though significant inroads were made during the
past decade, effluent treatment was not universally practiced by
1968.  Exhibit A-3 contains estimates  of the proportion of waste flow
treated by source  group at that point in time.  For the task at hand,
it will be assumed that  100 percent of all point effluents will be
treated by 1976.

Effluent quality after treatment by source group is very difficult to
estimate.  Some of the  complicating factors are discussed in
Chapter V of this  report.  They can be summarized by  recognizing
that within a given source group, different raw effluent qualities,
specific treatment processes and operating policies, and climatic
conditions will vary. Even so, after treatment effluent qualities
are recognized as critical determinants in comparing benefits and
costs accruing from alternative national pollution control policies.
Therefore, our beat estimate of after treatment quality under
wasteflows and treatments prevailing in 1968 is  presented in
Exhibit A-4.  However,  the reader is warned that the estimates
are subject to a very low degree of confidence due to very limited
and conflicting data.  Estimates are only presented for BOD, COD,
and TSS since these appear to be the only pollutants consistently
                              132

-------
                   Exhibit A- 2.  Treatment processes employed to control specific pollutants, by source
                                         group to meet current standards in
Pollutant
Biochemical oxygen demand
Chemicc 1 oxygen demand
Fecal coliforms
Dissolved solids
Suspended solids
pH
Toxic substances
Food & kindred
products
6, 8
3, 5, 6, 8
9
3
3, 5, 6, 8
2, 4
NA
Textile mill
products
6, 8
3, 6, 8
-
3
3, 6, 8
2, 4
3, 6
Lumber &c wood
products
6, 8
6, 8
-
NA
6, 8
4
6
Paper & allied Chemicals & allied
	 products 	 products
6, 8, 11 6, 7, 8, 9
6- 8' 11 1,3,5,6,7,8,9
-
NA 3
6, 8, 11 3, 5, 6, 8
4 2, 4
6 3, 6
U)
10
                                                                                continued	

-------
Exhibit A- 2.   Treatment processes employed to control specific pollutants,  by source
                     group to meet current standards in 1968*/  (continued)
Petroleum Rubber & Stone, clay Primary Fabricated metal
Pollutant fe coal plastics Leather & glass metals products
Biochemical oxygen demand 8, 12 6, 8 8 NA 6, 8
Chemical oxygen demand 1,3,5,8,12 3, 6, 8 3, 5, 8 NA 1. 3, 6, 8
Fecal coliforms - -
Dissolved solids 3 3 3 3 3, 10
Suspended solids 3, 5, 8 3, 6, 8 3, 5, 8 3, 6 3, 6, 8
pH 2, 4 2, 4 2, 4 4 2, 4
Toxic substances 2 - NA NA 3, 6, 10
3, 9
3, 9
-
3
3
2, 4
3
                                                               continued ....

-------
(ft
                  Exhibit A-2.   Treatment processes employed to control specific pollutants, by source
                                        group to meet current standards in 1968*/  (continued)
Pollutant
Biochemical oxygen demand
Chemical oxygen demand
Fecal coliforms
Dissolved solids
Suspended solids
PH
Toxic substances
Electrical
Machinery equipment
3 3, 9
3 3, 9
-
3 3
3 3
2, 4 2, 4
3 3
Transportation
equipment
3, 9
3, 9
-
3
3
2, 4
3
Municipal waste -
water
6, 8
6, 8
9
6, 8
6, 8
NA
-
— See text for definition of treatment process code numbers.
Source: Environmental Protection
Agency, The Economics of Clean
Water, Vols. I and II,
Washington, 1972.

-------
           Exhibit A- 3.
Municipal and industrial wastewater treatment practices in the U.S.
     Billion gallons of wasteflow by disposal method
1968
Source
Food and kindred products
Textiles
Lumber and wood products
Paper and allied products
Chemicals and allied products
Petroleum and coal
Rubber and plastics
Leather*
Stone, clay and glass
tu Primary metals
Fabricated metal products
Machinery
Electrical equipment
Transportation equipment
Domestic
Treated hr
industry
204.5
86.2
39.6
1,326
457
324
3.3
34.2
39.6
560
12.2
13.7
33
12.5
--
Sewered, by^treattnent level
f
Primary
89.8
27.0
1.8
35.2
40.7
0.9
3.6
11.6
7.5
18.8
21.8
8.2
29.2
14. 1
2,051.0
Secondary
155.8
46.7
3.0
61.1
70.6
1.5
6.2
20.2
13.1
32.6
37.9
14.1
50.5
24.4
3,556.0
Untreated
23.4
7.0
0.5
9.2
10.6
0.2
0.9
3.0
2.0
4.9
5.7
2.1
7.6
3.7
534.0
Ground
discharge
49.4
2.2
8.0
24. 1
28.4
4.7
1.2
1.4
12.7
16.4
0
0
4.6
4
--
Untreated
330.0
48.0
141.0
1.559.0
2,232.0
98.7
46.3
0
165.0
1, 187.0
32.4
61. 1
14, 1
101.0
--
Total
853
217
194
3,010
2,840
430
62
51
240
1,820
110
99
139
160
6,142
Industrial treatment plus sewerage exceeds total wasteflow for the leather industry.

Source: Distribution of sewered treatment, DPRA.
        Other data:  Environmental Protection Agency, The Economics of Clean Water, Vol.  I and II,
                     Washington, 1972.

-------
Exhibit A- 4.   Subjective estimates of after treatment wasteloads
              prevailing in 1968, by source group
Source group
Food and kindred products
Textile
Lumber and wood products
Paper and allied products
Chemicals and allied products
Petroleum and coal
Rubber and plastics
Leather
Stone, clay and glass
Primary metals
Fabricated metal products
Machinery
Electrical equipment
Transportation equipment
Munic ipalitiee

BOD
2,713
514
N.A.
5,260
6,055
78
13
131
N.A.
174
N.A.
31
46
61
5,097
Million pounds per
COD
7,297
600
N.A.
47,624
7,768
276
27
181
N.A.
8,101
N.A.
N.A.
N.A.
N.A.
8,343
year
TSS
4,015
69
N.A.
2,575
1,250
90
16
90
N.A.
1,392
N.A.
24.4
12.0
N.A.
3, 102
                             137

-------
reported on an after treatment basis.  Quality of treated effluents
by alternative abatement strategies should be viewed as another
research area  deserving attention.

       Total wasteflow, treated effluent concentrations and total
wasteloads under 1968 flow conditions and current standards are
estimated in Exhibit A-5.

Distribution of Wasteflows
       Regional distributions of industrial wasteflows are summar-
ized in Exhibits A-6 and A-7.  The former table^shows,  for each
industry,  the proportion of wasteflow discharged in each water use
region.  The latter table shows, for  each region, the proportion
of the regional wasteflow generated by each industrial sector.

Wasteloads Summarized
       Before proceeding to costs of control estimates,  a brief
summary of the data in Exhibits A-l through A-7 seems in order
and, for brevity, is presented below in outline format:

       1.  The total raw wasteload of any given pollutant varies
           substantially by source group.

       2.  The relative importance of a. specific pollutant varies
           substantially by source group.

       3.  Effluent treatment process requirements vary sub-
           stantially between source  groups and pollutants within
           source  groups.

       4.  In 1965, the degree of treatment varied tremendously
           between source groups.

       5.  Pollutant wasteloads under prevailing 1968 conditions
           varied substantially by source group but, in  general
           all sources were at relatively low levels of treatment.
           (We feel the data for the leather industry is misleading
           due to a high degree of overlap between private and
           municipal treatment leaving a substantial amount of
           low quality effluent).
                             138

-------
                   ExhibitA- 5.  Wasteflow, after treatment pollutant concentrations and after treatment
                                   wasteloads,  current standards in 1968,  by source group
co
NO
F
Item
Volumetric flow
(billion gallons/year)
Concentration after treatment
BOD (mg./£ )
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
COD (mg. /I)
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
Fecal coliform bacteria
(106MPN/100 ml)
Total dissolved solids (mg./jl)
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
TSS (mg./^)
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
pH
Toxic substances (mg. /^)
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
ood fa kindred
products
852

35
250
50
355
.09
900
7, 000
40
285
NA
NA
Textile mill
products
217

35
63
40
72
-
1, 100
2,000
20
36
NA
4
7
Lumber & wood
products
194

NA
NA
-
NA
NA
NA
NA
Paper & allied
products
3,015

30
754
60
1,510
-
NA
20
503
NA.
NA
Chemical & allied
products
2,840

20
474
35
829
-
NA
20
474
NA
NA

-------
             Exhibit A- 5.  Wasteflow, after treatment pollutant concentrations and after treatment
                            wasteloads, current standards in 1968,  by source group (continued)
Petroleum
Item & coal
Volumetric flow
(billion gallons/year)
Concentration
BOD (mg. / )
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
COD(mg./ )
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
Fecal coliform bacteria
£ (106MPN/100 ml)
Total dissolved solids (mg./ )
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
TSS (mg. / )
Total load {million Ibs/yr)
430


15
54
20
72
-
NA
20
72
Rubber 8t
plastics
62


10
5
20
10
-
NA
15
8
Stone, clay
Leather & glass
51 240


50 NA
21
NA NA
-
NA NA
40 NA
17
Primary Fabricated metal
metals products
1,820


5
76
40
607
-
NA
20
304
110


NA
NA
-
NA
NA
PH

Toxic substances (mg. / )
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
NA

NA
NA

NA
NA

NA
NA

NA
NA

NA
NA

NA

-------
    Exhibit A- 5.  Wasteflow, after treatment pollutant concentrations and after treatment
                     wasteloads, current standards in 1968, by source group (continued)
Item
Volumetric flow
(billion gallons/year)
Concentration after treatment
BOD (mg. / )
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
COD (mg. / )
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
Fecal coliform bacteria
(106MPN/100 ml)
Total dissolved solids (mg.
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
TSS(mg./ )
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
PH
Toxic substances (mg. / )
Total load (million Ibs/yr)
Source: Volumetric Flows:
•\r~l«, T -,-.,1 TT W.» c
Machinery
99

25
21
NA
-
/ ) NA
20
17
NA
NA
Electrical
equipment
139

40
46
NA
-
NA
15
17
NA
NA
Environmental Protection Agency, The
Transportation
equipment
160

30
40
NA
-
NA
NA
NA
NA
Economics of Clean
Municipal
wastewater
7,480

20
1,250
35
6.7
620
3,870
20
1,250
NA
NA
Water,
Other data:  DPRA.

-------
           Exhibit A- 6.  Regional distribution of industrial waste discharge,  by major industrial
                                               sectors,  1968
Regionally New Del.
Assignable Eng. &
Discharge Hu<£.
Meat Products
Dairy Products
Canned & Frozen Foods
All Other Food Products
Textile *ti11 Products
Paper S Allied Products
Chemical & Allied Products
Petroleum and Coal
Rubber & Plastic, n.e.c.
Primary Metals
Machinery exc. Electrical
Electrical Machinery
Transportation Equipment
Assignable Discharge
Percent of Industrial
Discharge, 1968
Preludes Hawaii
^Includes Alaska
99.0
98.8
93.1
84.4
98.5
98.7
99.0
92.0
92.9
96.6
99.9
96.9
97.0
96.5
100.0


.5
7.5
1.4
3.7
13.5
11.9
1.2
.1
15.8
.7
14.9
9.6
31.4
93.2
3,9
D

4.2
4.3
3.2
5.9
4.7
3.3
7.3
26.4
7.4
6.1
34.0
18.
3.
96.7
8.3
Chesa. East. Ohio Tenn.
Bay Gr. Lak. Riv. Cum.
St. Law.
2.7
4.9
2.5
.7
2.9
4.9
5.7
D
2.5
6.9
1.2
10.8
5.1
82.6
5.3
• Disclosure


1.0
8.9
3.9
1.0
.5
3.2
6.4
5.8
35.7
17.5
4.8
8.5
33.3
95.9
10.2
8.6
5.1
2.3
4.0
2.4
2.4
16.6
2.3
6.8
29.4
9.0
25.6
4.6
98.1
16.1
not available due


1.5
.6
D
.2
6.3
3.1
9.3
—
D
.5
.8
1.0
.6
91.5
3.8
- - '_ - 	 	
S.E.
11.6
2.3
29.0
3.4
65.7
28.9
4.7
2.0
6.9
1.7
.7
4.1
1.7
97.8
7.7
to disclosure


West
Gr. Lak
2.8
12.5
5.3
9.8
D
7.8
2.7
13.0
8.4
25.2
12.5
9.0
7.1
96.1
12.7
Upper
. Miss.
30.9
24.7
2.9
14.0
.5
6.0
2.1
1.2
4.3
2.6
19.8
5.
2.1
88.7
4.1
constraints on


Lower
Miss. Mo.
1.7
2.8
1.9
11.7
1.4
2.7
8.0
10.2
3.3
0
.3
.5
D
78.7
5.2
U. S.

17.9
4.3
.9
6.7
—
1.0
.4
1.6
0
.4
.2
.8
D
81.3
1.0
Bureau

Ark. West.
W&R Gulf
6.7 2.8
4.7 1.
1.8 .8
.3 1.5
D D
3,8 2.5
.9 31.5
1.1 27.5
.9 0
.6 3.4
.3 .7
.9 D
.5 5.0
95.7 99.3
1.3 13.3
of Census

Colo.
Basin
0
D
D
0
D
.1
D
D
0
.2
D
D
D
61.7
0.1


Gr.
Basin.
D
1.3
D
D
D
D
0
.1
D
D
D
D
D
8.2
0.2


. Ca,.1
3.5
7.0
20.5
20.3
.6
2.1
.6
8.4
.9
.2
.7
3.0
2.2
81.6
2.8


Pacf.2
N.M.
2.6
6.4
16.7
1.2
D
15.0
1.6
.2
0
1.2
D
D
D
87.6
4.0


Source:  Environmental Protection Agency, The Economics of Clean Water, Vols.  I and II, Washington, 1972,

-------
                    Exhibit A- 7.   Sources of regional industrial waste discharge,  by region, 1968
                                                   PERCENT OF REGIONAL DISCHARGE BY INDUSTRY
UJ
New
Eng,
Meat Products .1
Dairy Products .7

Canned * Frozen Foods .3

All Other Food Products 2.5
Textile Mill Products 3.3
Paper * Allied Products 44.1
Chemical * Allied Products 9.3
Petroleum and Coal .1
Rubber & Plastic, n.e.c. 3.6
Primary Metals 5.9
Machinery exc. Electrical 4.8
Electrical Machinery 2.0
Transportation Equipment 16.5
Assignable Discharge 93.2
1
Includes Hawaii
2
Includes Alaska
Source: Environmental
Del.
.4
.2

.6

4.0
.5
5.8
25.7
26.9
.8
24.0
5.2
1.8
.8
96.7


D

Chesa East
Bay Gr. Lak.
.4 .1
.3 .3

.4 .3

.5 .3
.5
13.4 4.5
31.7 18.4
D 4.8
.4 3.1
31.0 56.1
.3 .6
1.7 .7
2.0 6.7
82.6 95.9


= Disclosure

Protection Agency
Ohio Tenn. S.E. West. Upper Low Ark Ue^t
Riy Cunb. Gr. Lak. Hiss. Miss. Ho. W&R Gulf'
•4 -3 ]-° -2 5.3 .2 12.5 3.6 .1
.1 - 1 4 77 o i f t
'••* •' 1.61.4
.1 - 3.2 4 K o ft -i .,
-H •" .3 .8 1.2
•8 -2 '-5 2-4 T.6 7.6 22.6 .7 .4
-1 !•« 8.1 0 .1 .3 I D D
2.1 11.8 54.6 9.0 21.4 7.7 14.3 42.7 2.7
30.2 72.6 18.0 6.2 15.0 45.0 12.3 20.9 69.2
T-2 - 2.3 8.7 2.5 16.6 13.6 7.4 17.6
•4 ' -8 -6 -9 .6 D .6 Q
60-1 4-1 7-2 65.3 20.7 0 14.0 15.5 8.4
•7 "3 •' 1-2 6.2 .1 .3 .3 .1
K3 -2 -4 •« 1.0 .1 .6 .6 0
•6 -4 -5 1-1 1.1 D D .8 .8
98.1 91.5 97.8 96.1 88.7 78.7 81.3 95.7 99.9


not available due to disclosure constraints on
Bureau of Census
, The Economics of Clean Water, Vols. land
Colo. Gr. pacf._
Basin Bas. Cal.* N.K
-------
       6.   Our interpretations of current standards and associated
            wasteloads after treatment imply that current standards
            applied in 1968 would have greatly reduced the after
            treatment wasteload as compared to prevailing con-
            ditions at that time.

       7.   Although not estimated herein, wasteflows in 1976 under
            full compliance will still contribute sizeable pollutant
            loads to surface waters.

       8.   Regional wasteflows and composition of wasteflows are
            of such a nature that regional considerations in a
            national pollution control assessment cannot be ignored.

Costs of Control

       Capital and annual operation and maintenance costs required
to meet current standards  in  1968 are presented in Exhibit A-8.
These data are supplied by EPA (1) as the maximum possible cost.
However, the costs are based upon prevailing water efficiency and
wasteflow conditons in 1968.  Also, from various industrial firms
and trade organizations we have seen substantially higher estimates.
We  feel EPA's maximum cost number for 1968 is probably better
than the  ones assuming structural changes resulting in substantial
increases in water use efficiency and modification of wasteflow levels

       For comparative purposes, the estimated replacement  value
of industrial and municipal  treatment facilities are presented in Ex-
hibit A-9.  Again, the actual  1968 condition falls considerably  below
the  current standards  case.   This condition is summarized in Exhibit
A-10 which reports capital  requirements in 1968 to meet current
standards, prevailing 1968 treatment configurations and the amount
that prevailing costs fell short of current standards.  Also,  the capital
cost of meeting economic and population expansion between 1968 and
1976 are presented in the latter table.  Please note that the  1976 capital
requirements are  stated in  constant 1967 dollars and that the inflation
rate for  construction costs in the wastewater treatment segment of the
economy has risen much more rapidly than for the economy on the
average.  Wastewater capital costs during 1968-71 rose roughly one-
third.  Total annual municipal and industrial pollution control costs
for  full compliance in 1976 (including annualized capital cost) will
probably exceed 4.5 billion 1967 constant dollars.
                          144

-------
Exhibit A- 8.  Cost of meeting current standards under \Sfe8 wasteflow conditions in millions of
                                          1967 dollars
Pollutant
treated/cost
component
Biochemical
oxygen demand
Capital
Annual O&M
Chemical
oxygen demand
Capital
Annual O&M
Fecal coliforms
Capital
Annual O&M
Dissolved solids
Capital
Annual O&M
Suspended solids
Capital
Annual O&M
PH
Capital
Annual O&M
Toxic substances
Capital
Annual O&M
Total cost
Capital
Annual O&M
Food & kindred
products


781
15


835
22

4
1

40
2

835
22

158
7

N.A.
N.A.

997
58
Textile mill
products


216
9


239
10

0
0

23
1

239
10

13
1

149
8

251
11
Lumber & wood
products


163
8


163
8

0
0

N.A.
N.A.

163
8

23
2

91
6

186
10
Paper & allied
products


1,170
97


1,170
97

0
0

N.A.
N.A.

1, 170
97

381
17

490
58

1,551
112
Chemicals &
allied products


434
22


2, 100
112

0
0

350
52

804
102

338
16

475
61

2,436
128

-------
Exhibit A- 8.   Cost of meeting Current standards  under 1968 wasteflow conditions in millions of
                                           1967 dollars (continued)
Pollutant
treated/cost Fabricated metal
component products Machinery
Biochemical
oxygen demand
Capital
Annual O&M
Chemical
oxygen demand
Capital
Annual O&M
Fecal coliforms
Capital
*>. Annual O&M
Dissolved solids
Capital
Annual O&M
Suspended solids
Capital
Annual OfcM
PH
Capital
Annual O&M
Toxic substances
Capital
Annual O&M
Total cost
Capital
Annual OfcM

96
9

96
9

0
0

94
9
94
9
28
3

94
9

124
13

74
8

74
8

0
0

74
8
74
8
25
3

74
8

100
11
Electrical
equipment

96
11

96
11

0
0

94
10
94
10
33
3

94
10

130
14
Transportation
equipment

86
12

86
12

0
0

84
11
84
11
37
4

84
11

J23
16
Municipalities

16,810
629

16,810
629

0
2

N.A.
N.A.
16,810
629
N.A.
N.A.

0
0

16,810
631

-------
          Exhibit A- 8.   Cost of meeting current standards under 1%8 wasteflow conditions in millions of
                                                      ~ dollars (continued)
Pollutant
treated/cost
component
Biochemical
oxygen demand
Capital
Annual OfeM
Cheinical oxygen
demand
Capital
Annual OKtM
Fecal coliforms
Capital
Annual O&M
Dissolved solids
Capital
Annual O&M
Suspended solids
Capital
Annual OfeM
PH
Capital
Annual OfcM
Toxic substances
Capital
Annual O&M
Total cost
Capital
Annual O&M
Petroleum
and coal


650
24


1, 066
47

0
0

84
11

90
11

30
2

12
00

1,096
48
Rubber and
plastics


71
4


86
5

0
0

16
1

86
5

10
1

0
0

96
6
Leather


27
1


66
4

0
0

38
2

66
4

21
1

N.A.
N.A.

87
4
Stone clay
and glass


N.A.
N.A.


N.A.
N.A.

0
0

136
17

148
17

34
4

N.A.
N.A.

182
21
Primary metals


126
8


1,240
126

0
0

473
92

475
99

258
21

533
96

1,620
147
Source:  Environmental Protection Agency, The Economics of Clean Water, Vols. I and II, Washington, 1972.

-------
Exhibit A- 9.   Cost of reported municipal and industrial treatment,  1968
Cost in millions of 1967 dollars
Source Group
Food and kindred products
Textiles
Lumber and wood products
Paper and allied products
Chemical and allied products
Petroleum and coal
Rubber and plastics
Leathe r
Stone, clay and glass
Primary metals
Fabricated metal products
Machine ry
Electrical equipment
Transportation equipment
Manuf a c tu r in g
Municipal
Capital
replacement
value
194
49
10
530
343
342
3
17
20
216
7
15
24
17
1,787
12,392
Annual
operation
15
4
2
65
63
73
0
2
2
35
0
1
2
1
263
539
 Source:  Environmental Protection Agency, The Economics of Clean
         Vols. I and II, Washington,  1972.  "  "               "    ~
                            148

-------
   Exhibit A- 10.  Municipal and industrial waste treatment requirements,  1968 and 1976
                             capital cost, millions of 1967 dollars
Replacement value of

Source group
Food and kindred products
Textiles
Lumber and wood products
Paper and allied products
Chemicals and allied products
Petroleum, and coal
Rubber and plastics
Leather
Stone, clay and glass
Primary metals
Fabricated metal products
Machinery
Electrical equipment
Transportation equipment
Manufacturing
Municipal
*Rate of improvement in water
Requirement
1968
997
251
186
1,551
2,436
1,096
96
87
182
1,620
124
100
130
123
8,966
16,810
capital
supplied, 1968
Industrial Municipal
194
49
10
530
343
342
3
17
20
216
7
15
24
17
1,787
N.A.
productivity is greater than
Source: Adapted from: Environmental Protection
Agency,
315
64
2
79
192
7
23
17
22
126
51
49
92
92
1, 132
12,392
rate of growth
Deficit
1968
488
138
174
942
1,901
747
70
53
140
1,278
66
36
14
14
6,047
4,418
of output.
The Economics of Clean
Growth
1968-76
189
82
0*
145
572
55
38
18
27
560
48
5
34
13
1,786
2,572

Water, Vols.
Requirement
1976
1, 186
333
186
1,696
3,008
1, 151
134
105
209
2, 180
172
105
164
136
10,752
19,382

I and II,
Washington, 1972.

-------
Benefits £rom Pollution Control

       The reductions  in national pollution costs (benefits) associ-
ated with the above costs of control data are not available at this
time.  However, some regional studies are available.  Also,
some subjective estimates  as to the form of the national pollution
cost reductions  can be  made.  These are summarized below:

       Exhibit A-11 represents a restatement of regional benefits
obtained in three of the more comprehensive studies currently
available.  Note that the benefits are only referenced in terms of
percentage distribution of monetary benefits accruing from pollution
control among beneficial uses.  Although the original studies re-
ported actual dollar estimates,  such estimates are not useful at
this  juncture since they cannot be used as a basis for estimates  of
absolute national welfare (see generally Chapters I-III  of this re-
port for substantiation  of this conclusion).

       Perhaps the most outstanding characteristic of these studies
is representative of nearly all studies  examining comprehensive
benefits from pollution control -- empirical estimations of health,
ecological  and intangible esthetics are absent.  Another problem is
highlighted since none of the studies examine substitution  effects.
The  Anondaga Lake study is further limited since it appears only
one industrial firm of significant size in the area utilizes  surface
water as a supply and the municipal benefits were obtained by sub-
stituting water from one lake with water from another lake of equal
quality.  Municipal benefits were then calculated as the total cost
of preuse treatment.  Due to these shortcomings, the following  dis-
cussion will  consider only the Ohio and Maumee studies.

       In apology to the original investigators,  we readily admit
that  while  we have  stated benefit distributions in terms of a water
quality range, they estimated benefits as a  function of degree of
effluent  removal.   Any interpretation errors resulting from this
transformation  rests solely upon those  preparing this report and
not the original investigators.

       In search of a way to make thie data  in Exhibit A-11 take on
more realism,  it was felt an adjustment for substitution should  be
made --at least for recreation.  Since sources examining the
magnitude  of substitution effects in water-based recreation are  not
                             150

-------
                 Exhibit A- 11. Distribution of monetary benefits accruing from water pollution control among
                                beneficial uses, selected studies, by level of water quality
        Beneficial use
                                               Ohio Basin
Low -m edium
water quality
Medium -high
water quality
                                        Maurnee Basin
                                               Onondaga
Low-medium
water quality
Medium-high
water quality
                                                                                                       Me dium - hi gh
                                                                                                       water quality
Health
Production
   Municipal water treatment
   Domestic use
   Industrial use
   Navigation
   Commercial fishing
        Total

Tangible esthetics
   Recreation
   Property values
        Total

Ecological and intangible esthetics

     TOTAL
                                          2.6
                                          6.3
                                          6.9
                                          2.2
                                          0.0
                                         18.1
                                         77.8
                                          4.2
                                         81.9
                                       100.0
                    3.3
                    8.0
                    8.8
                    2.8
                    0.0
                   23.0
                  74.3
                   2.7
                  77.0
                 100.0
                    24.2
                    31.7
                    13.9
                     0.0
                     0. 0
                    69.8
                    28.7
                     1.5
                    30.2
                   100.0
                   28.9
                   25.4
                   21.6
                    0.0
                    0.0
                   75.9
                   23.0
                    1.2
                   24. 1
                  100.0
                     12.8

                      3.5
                      0.9
                      0.0
                     17.3
                     60.9
                     21.8
                     82.7
                    100.0
*
—  Substantially revised by DPRA from originally published data so that meaningful comparisons could be made.

Sources:  Ohio Basin:  H. C.  Bramer, The Economic Aspects__of the Water Pollution Abatement Program in the Ohio
          River Valley, Doctoral Dissertation, University of Pittsburg, I960.
          Maumee Basin:  Jack V. Matson, Coat of Industrial and Municipal Water Pollution Abatement in the Maumee
          River Basin, Master's  Thesis,  University of Toledo,  1968.
          Onondaga Lake:  N. L.  Nemerow and R.  C.  Faro, ''Measurement of the  Total Dollar Benefit of Water
          Pollution Control," Benefits of Water Quality Enhancement, Environmental Protection Agency, Washington,
          1970,  pp. 39-144.

-------
available, we hypothesized it could range anywhere from 0 to 100
percent.  As a midpoint,  we assumed 50 percent of the original
benefit estimation for recreation would be lost due to substitution
effects.  The adjusted benefit distributions under this assumption
are depicted in Exhibit A-12.  Even then, recreation comprises a
very large share of total  benefits.   These relationships for the
Ohio and Maumee basins  have been averaged and displayed geo-
graphically in Exhibit A-13.

       The curves in Exhibit A-13 are interesting not only in
terms of magnitudes  but also in terms of slope.  Simply stated,
they imply that as water quality changes, beneficial uses are im-
pacted in different  proportions.

       Utilizing the Ohio and Maumee  studies as a base,  subjective
benefit distributions were derived which  included both health and
ecological and intangible  esthetic impacts.  First, the two studies
were averaged and it was assumed the result is fairly representative
of the U. S. as a whole.  Secondly,  recreation benefits were re-
duced 50 percent, as noted above,  to adjust for substitution.  Estim-
ating ecological and intangible benefits were most difficult.  After
considerable deliberation, it was concluded that the best indicator
for the value of these benefits was  recreation benefits before sub-
stitution considerations.  For current  purposes we feel it is reason-
able to assume that ecological and intangible benefits are at least
as large as the recerational benefits as calculated in the base studies
Given production, tangible esthetics and  ecological and intangible
esthetic estimates, health benefits were  estimated through obser-
vation of national health data and a good  deal of subjectivity.  A
further subjective modification was required to include irrigation
which was not a beneficial use in the base studies. The resultant
estimates are presented in Exhibit A-14. The high proportion of
benefits allocated to each category will no doubt be criticized by
some as being too high and by others as  being too low.  Yet, we
feel they are  reasonable and accurately reflect the evidence pre-
sented by available studies. Note that the study team attempted to
find documented  evidence of such relationships but hypothesized
any existence of  such relationships for those cases where adequate
documentation was not available.

       To further investigate the importance of specific pollutants
by beneficial use, the potential damages  matrix in Exhibit A-15 was
                             152

-------
                  Exhibit A- 12. Adjusted distribution of monetary benefits accruing from water pollution
                               control among beneficial uses, by level of water quality*/
Beneficial use
Health
Production
Municipal water treatment
Domestic use
Industrial use
Navigation
Commercial fishing
Total
Tangible esthetics
Recreation
Property values
Total
Ecological and intangible esthetics
TOTAL
Ohio
Low -me dium
water quality
-

4.2
10.3
11.4
3.7
0.1
29.6

63.6
6.8
70.4
-
100.0
Basin
Medium -high
water quality
-

5.2
12.7
14.0
4.5
0. 1
36.7

59.1
4.2
63.3
-
100.0
Maumee Basin
Low-medium
water quality
--

28.3
37.0
16.2
0.0
0.0
81.5

16.8
1.7
18.5
-
100.0
Medium -high
water quality
-

32.7
28.7
24.4
0.0
0.0
85.7

13.0
1.3
14.3
-
100.0
Onondaga Lake*/
Medium -high
water quality
-

18.4
-
5. 1
1.3
0.0
24.9

43.8
31.4
75.1
-
100.0
—  Assumes 50 percent of recreation benefits are eliminated when substitution impacts are included in the analysis.

-------
          Exhibit A-13.   Average adjusted monetary benefit distribution for the Ohio and Maumee basins.
 Percent of
total benefits
 Percent of
total benefits
uu
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10

100
Without substituion of recreational benefits
90
80
70
. 	 *ecreation 6°
T°tal tan^j3thlt2£5zS^^ 50
40-
30
— — _ ^Domestic 20
	 fn'dus'trial ^
• • *
With substitution of recreational benefits (5



^ 	 	

?5JUt|ngibIe esthetics
"" 	 ~ 	 ^SSJeation""" — 	

	 fndust rial

             Low-medium                 Medium high
                           Water Quality
            Low-medium                 Medium high
                           Water Quality

-------
   Exhibit A- 14. Subjective estimate of distribution of social benefits
     accruing from water pollution control among beneficial uses;
                       by level of water quality
Beneficial use
                                             % of Benefits
Low-medium
water quality
Medium-high
water quality
Health

Production
   Municipal water treatment
   Domestic use
   Industrial use
   Irrigation & animal health
   Navigation
   Commercial fishing
       Total

Tangible Esthetics
   Recreation
   Property values
       Total

Ecological & Intangible Esthetics

     TOTAL
    4.5
   10.0
   14.0
    8.5
    4.0
    0.5
    0.1
   37.1
   18.5
    2.0
   20.5

   37.9

  100.0
    4.0
    12.0
    12.5
    11.5
     3.0
     1.5
     0.1
    40.6
    17.0
     1.5
    18.5

    36,9

   100.0
                                155

-------
            Exhibit A- 15.  State-of-the-arts of pollution-beneficial use potential relationships, over all ranges of water quality
HEALTH
PRODUCTION




Industrial

BOD
COD
pH
Coliform
Nitrogen
Phosphate
Toxic Sub.*/
Hardness
TDS
TSS**
Temperature
Oil
Color
Turbidity
Odor
Taste
Radionucles
Floating Solids
Human
Health
Mun. Preuse
Treatment
OU ID
OU ID
ID ID
ID ID
ID ID
OU ID
ID ID
ID ID
ID ID
ID ID
OU OU
ID ID
OU ID
ID ID
OD ID
OD ID
ID ID
OU ID
a o
s '•§
c   pollutant has an effect upon usability
#*/                                                   0  =>  pollutant has no effect upon usability within water quality ranees normally
—  Includes sellable solids.-                                      t            ,.,-LLJ         _,
                                                      D =>  a pollutant-use relationship has been documented
                                                      U =>  documentation of a pollutant-use relationship (or lack of one) has not been
                                                            (or lack of one) seems plausible

References:  1.  "Water Quality Criteria. " FWPCA. 1968.
            Z.  Todd, "The Water Encyclopedia." 1970.
            3.  "Manual on Industrial Water and Industrial Waste Water. ". ASTM Special Technical Publication No. 148-1, 1966.
            4.  Zajic, J. I., "Water Pollution — Disposal and Reuse, " 1971.
            5.  Lund, H. F. ,  "Industrial Pollution Control Handbook," 1971.
            6.  "Cleaning our Environment the Chemical Basis for Action, " Am. Chem. Soc. 1969.


                  Acknowledgement:  Dr.  Dennis Tihansky, Economic Analysis  Branch,  EPA,

                                           provided invaluable assistance in the preparation of the
                                           benefit  matrix.
encounte red

found, but such a relationship

-------
multiplied by the average of the appropriate beneficial use distri-
butions in Exhibit A-14.  The resultant subjective ranking is pre-
sented in Exhibit A-16.  In most cases the individual cell values
seem plausible.  Also the ranking of beneficial uses based upon
the average row seems consistent with anticipated results.
However, the row (pollutant) ranks are not realistic.  The
problem here is hopefully one of not including indicators of
pollutant and prevalence and intensity rather than basic  incon-
sistencies in the ranking matrix.

       Hence,  our subjective ranking of beneficial uses is the
order in which they appear in Exhibit A-16 with ecological and
intangible esthetics being the most important.  Commercial fish-
ing is the least important.

       One  last step was taken to  subjectively estimate  the relative
importance  of specific pollutants.  By adjusting the  row rankings
in Exhibit A-16 by subjective prevalence and intensity factors,  a
final ranking was  obtained and summarized in Exhibit A-17.  It
should be noted that these rankings were made with  respect  to man-
made pollutants.  Impacts from natural pollution are not reflected
in the rankings.  However, we have attempted to account for both
source point and non-point  pollution in both the subjective  benefit
distributions and pollutant rankings.

       At the risk of redundancy,  we again point out that these data
are highly subjective.   The subjective rankings  of pollutants are
especially weak in that respect.  However, it is our hope that they
may be useful to those faced with allocating funds for future studies.

 Exhibit A-17.  Subjective ranking of specific pollutants  by their
                relative impact on beneficial uses
Group I:     Organics --BOD,  COD

Group II:    Nutrients -- nitrogen and phosphates

Group III:   Suspended and dissolved solids

Group IV:   Turbidity, pH,  temperature

Group V:    Fecal coliforms, oil, toxic substances, floating solids,
             color,  odor

Group VI:   Hardness, taste radioactivity
                            157

-------
                            Exhibit A-16.  Subjective ranking of beneficial use-pollutant soical cost potential relationships-'
                                                                                                                          I/
Beneficial Use
Pollutant
TSS
Oil
Turbidity
Floating solids
Color
TDS
pH ,
j /
Toxic sub.—
Nitrogen
Coliform
Radionucles
COD
BOD
Phosphate
Odor
Hardness
Temperature
Taste
Total
Average
4/
Density—
Ecologic fc
intangible
esthetics
.374
.374
.374
.374
.374
. 187
.187
.187
.374
.374
. 374
.374
.374
.374
.374
.187
.187
.187
5.610
.312
.833
Recre -
ation
. 1775
.1775
.1775
. 1775
. 1775
. 1775
. 1775
. 1775
.1775
.1775
. 1775
. 1775
.1775
.1775
. 1775
0
. 1775
.0888
2.9288
.163
.917
Municipal
preuse
treatment
. 11
. 11
. 11
. 11
. 11
. 11
. 1 1
. 11
. 11
. 11
. 11
. 11
. 11
. 11
. 11
. 11
0
. 11
1.870
. 104
.944
Domestic
use
. 1325
. 1325
. 1325
. 13Z5
. 1325
. 1325
. 1325
. 1325
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
. 1325
. 1325
0
1.325
.074
.556
Industry
Use
.10
.08
. 08
.10
.07
.10
. 10
.09
.02
. 02
.01
.02
. 02
.02
.01
.08
. 04
.01
.970
.054
.539
Health
.0425
.0425
.0425
0
0
.0425
.0425
.0425
.0425
.0425
.0425
0
0
0
0
.0425
0
0
.425
.024
.556
Ag.
Irri-
gation
.035
.035
0
0
0
.035
.035
.035
.035
.035
. 035
.035
.035
0
0
.035
.035
0
.420
.023
.667
Property
values
. 0175
.0175
.0175
. 0175
.0175
. 0175
.0175
. 0175
.0175
. 0175
. 0175
. 0175
.0175
. 0175
.0175
0
.0175
0
.280
.016
.889
Navi-
gation
.01
.01
0
.01
0
.01
. 01
0
.01
0
0
.01
.01
.01
0
.01
0
0
.100
.006
.556
Com-
mercial
fishing
.001
. 001
, 001
.001
.001
. 001
. 001
. 001
.001
.001
.001
.001
. 001
.001
.001
.001
.001
. 001
.018
.001
1.000
Total-
1. 000
.980
.935
.922
.882
.813
.813
.793
. 788
. 778
. 768
. 745
. 745
.710
.690
.598
. 590
.397

.793

—  Cell rank equals product of row rank and column rank.  Row rank is
   uses.  Column rank equals  one if pollutant is  significant for that use,

—  Maximum  possible  total value  is 1.0.

—  Includes heavy metals.
—  Density = average value for column/highest possible value for a cell
                                                                    158
determined by distribution of total social benefits
,  otherwise zero.  Maximum possible cell rank is
in that column.
among beneficial
1.0.

-------
                         References Cited
1.   Environmental Protection Agency,  The Economics of Clean "Water,
     Vols.  I and II, Washington, 1972.

2,   Bramer, H. C.,  The Economic Aspects of the Water Pollution
     Abatement Program in the Ohio^River Valley, Doctoral Dissertation,
     University of Pittsburg,  I960.

3.   Matson, Jack V. , Cost of Industrial and Municipal Water Pollution
     Abatement in the  Maumee River Basin, Master's Thesis, University
     of Toledo, 1968.

4.   Nemerow, N.  L.  and Faro, R.  C., "Measurement of the Total Dollar
     Benefit of "Water Pollution Control," Benefits of Water Quality
     Enhancement, Environmental Protection Agency, Washington,  1970,
     pp.  39-144.
                                159

-------
                        APPENDIX B


          Water Quality Associated Health Impacts


       Phase I of this project included a brief section on the health
impacts  emanating from water quality degradation.  This general
area represents  one are of water quality management which has re-
ceived some attention in the past but complete documentation is
presently lacking.  The intent here is to briefly explore these water
quality impacts,  present data  sources,  procedures, and to so far
as possible hypothesize the magnitude of water quality associated
health impacts.
 The Extent of the Health Impacts

        There is substantial and convincing evidence of undesirable
 impacts on human health resulting from lack of water quality control.
 Microbiological, chemical, physical and radioactive pollutants are
 of concern with respect to human health.  It has been estimated
 that in some countries  one -third to one -half of the hospital beds
 are  occupied by patients suffering from waterborne diseases  (1).

       A review of water-related disease outbreaks in the United
 States has shown that during the fifteen year period 1946-1960,  there
 were 228 known outbreaks of disease attributed to drinking water.
 To be considered an  outbreak,  a death or at least two cases  of the
 disease had to be reported.  Thus the resulting statistics do not
 include single cases  of waterborne diseases.  The data show 25,984
 cases of illness associated with waterborne diseases  that occurred
 during the period.  This gives an annual rate of 1. 1 waterborne
 illnesses per 100,000 population served by public water supplies
       This  rate includes outbreaks of typhoid,  gastroenteritis,
infectious hepatitis, salmonellosis and a few other diseases.  How-
ever, it does not include methemoglobinemia, for example, since
this usually occurs in individual cases of infants.   There are  some
other human health impacts associated with water quality which
have only recently come to attention of health officials.  There
are also many  cases of water related health problems which
are not reported by the victim as well as long-term effects which
                            160

-------
may occur over a number of years which have not yet been ade-
quately analyzed.  Thus the annual rate mentioned above of 1. 1
waterborne illnesses per 100,000 population must be considered
the lowest possible rate for that period (1946-60). Exhibit B-l
presents the incidence of water borne diseases in the U.S. during
this period.
Exhibit B-l.  Waterborne diseases in the United States,  1946-60
Disease

Gastroenteritis
Typhoid
Infectious hepatitis
Diarrhea
Shigellosis
Salmonellosis
Amebiasis
Other

Total
Outbreaks
Number
126
39
23
16
11
4
2



Cases
Number
13,630
506
930
5, 160
5,653
24


45

25,984
Source: The Nation's Water Resourcej^ United State Water Resource
        Council, Washington,  D. C., 1968.  p.  5-4-1.
Major Water Quality Variables Associated with Health
Impacts

       The water quality variables currently being measured in the
United States which are known to be most important in terms of health
impacts are the levels of fecal coliforms,  the biochemical oxygen
demand {BOD), the dissolved oxygen level (DO), dissolved solids
and levels of toxic chemicals such as mercury.

       Biochemical oxygen demand is a surrogate indicator of  the
effect of a combination of substances and conditions.  It is a measure
of the amount of dissolved oxygen that will be depleted from the water
during the natural biological assimilation  of organic pollutants.  Swiftly
                             161

-------
moving streams have a greater capacity,  for reaeration and for
preventing the accumulation of high BOD materials in bottom de-
posits than do sluggish streams or reservoirs.

       Dissolved oxygen is one of the most commonly used para-
meters of water quality.  Low levels of DO adversely affect fish
and other aquatic life and total absence  of DO leads to the develop-
ment of an anaerobic condition with attendant odor and esthetic
problems.  The ability of water to hold  DO decreases with increases
in temperature or dissolved solids (3).

       Fecal coliform counts show the level of fecal  contamination
of water.  These counts are used as indicators of the potential of
the water for transmission of viral diseases.

        Levels of chemicals in water can often be measured directly.
Health Impacts Associated with Specified Pollutants

        The following Exhibit (Exhibit B-2) presents a number of
health impacts resulting from lack of water quality control, the
method of transmission to the population, the specific pollutants
involved in each impact and  the sources  of these pollutants.  The
most appropriate water quality variables which are  currently
thought to be reliable indicators of the potential of the water for
transmission of the pollutant and creation of undesirable health
impacts,  or spreading  of diseases (such as virus diseases) are
also given.
                             162

-------
                          Exhibit B-2

   Methods of Transmission of the Pollutants to the Population


       The methods of transmission of the pollutants to the population

may be categorized as:

       1.  Pollutants which enter throug the public water supply.
                a.  Chemical impurities
                b.  Bacteria, viruses, etc.

       2.  Pollutants which enter through the food supply (where
           the food is polluted by water, such as a buildup of
           chemicals in fish which will be consumed by humans).
                a.  Chemicals in water supplies
                b.  Bacteria and viruses in water supplies

       3.  Effects of polluted water on transmission of com-
           municable diseases by
                a.  Natural populations (such as mosquitoes)
                b.  Domesticated animals
                c.  Humans

       4.  Pollutants which enter the body through direct (bodily)
           contact with the water.

       5.  Pollutants which lead to ecological changes  which affect
           human physical and/or psychological health.
                               163

-------
Health impacts
  (Damages)

Alteration of liver
function,  hydroperi-
cardium (accumula-
tion of fluid in sac
surrounding heart)
and chloracne (skin
eruptions).

Eye irritation
Method of Transmission
(2)  Through the food chain
         '
as
(4) Bodily contact with
water
Schistosomiasis-      (1) Enters through the
(rash stomach pain,   intestine when person
dizziness, damage to  drinks contaminated
internal organs,
anemia, cancer of
the liver)
water, and
(4) Enters through the
skin of swimmers  or
waders  in contamin-
ated •water.
Pollutants
Polychlorinated
biphenyls
Indicator (Water
Quality Variable)

PCB level (meas-
ured directly)
Too high or low a
pH level (and buffer
capacity of water)

Schistosomiasis eggs in
feces from infected
humans develop into
larvae in streams or
ponds and seek an
Australorbis glabratus
snail.   They burrow
into the snail and emerge
as free, swimming organ-
isms which can infect man
if a victim is iound within
30 to 36 hours.
pH level (meas-
ured directly)
Coliform count -
(Can be used as
an indicator of
the potential for
transmis sion)
Source  of Pollutant

Industrial and municipal
discharges to inland and
coastal waters.
Discharges of acids
or bases, acid mine
d ra ina ge

Human feces
     —' Number codes in this column refer to categories described on  page 4 of this section.

-------
 Health impacts
   (Damages)

 Hepatitis
 (inflamation of
 liver)
 Cholera (diarrhea,
 vomiting, .nuscle
 c ramps, low blood
 pressure)
 Malaria (fever,
 chills , back pain)
Method of Transmission

(16, 26) a virus which is
spread through contami-
nated water on food (esp.
raw oysters or clams)
(Ib, 2b) through water
supply or food supply,
ingestion of food or water
contaminated with Vo
cholerae

(3)  Transmitted by
Anopheles mosquitoes
    Pollutants
Virus growing in pol-
luted water
Contamination of supply
with V. choJerae
(through fecal contami-
nation)
Mosquitoes breeding in
swampy areas
Indicator (Water
Quality Variable)

Coliform count
(is used as an
indicator of poten-
tial for trans-
mission of virus)

Coliform count
Dissolved oxygen
BOD
Phosphates (alga
growth is faster)
Source of Pollutant

Human feceo
contaminated garbage
                                                                                                 Human feces
(Stagnant water)
for ex.  alga   growth
which stabilizes water
surface
Ul

-------
Health impacts
  (Damages)

Leptospirosis
(fever, muscular
pain, nausea)

Salmone llo s i s
(stomach upsets,
diarrhea,  chills,
fever)

Minamata disease
(mercury poisoning)
(weakening of mus-
cles,  loss of vision,
paralysis, coma
death)
Method of Transmission

(4) Bodily contact with
water
(Ib) 2b) contaminated
water or food supply
(2a) food chain such as
in fish, methyl mercury
is concentrated in food
chains because it is fat
soluble.
     Pollutants
Microscopic parasites
- leptospira
Salmonellae bacteria
which breed in food or
water
Mercury (Primarily in
the form of methyl
mercury)
Indicator (Water
Quality Variable)

Coliform count
Coliform. count
Measure mercury
directly in water
(or fish)
Source  of Pollutant.

Urine of infected
animals
Garbage, human feces
Industrial discharges

-------
  Health impacts
    (Damages)

  Renal effects
  itai - itai
  possibly hyper-
  tension
  (cadmium effects
  both acute and
  chronic)
  (cancer has been
  produced in ani-
  mals)

  Methemo globinemia
  (reduces ability of
  the blood to trans-
£ port oxygen)

  Endemic f lucres is
  dental and skeletal
  (chronic toxic effects
  on tooth enamel and
  bones; increased
  density of bone, stiff-
  ness of spine,  limita-
  tion of movement)
Method of Transmission

(2a) - through the food
chain
    Pollutants
Indicator (Water
Quality Variable)
                                                                           Source of Pollutant
Cadmium
Measure cadmium    Industrial discharges
(la) - through water
supply
(la) through water supply
(also food supply)
Nitrites and nitrates
Fluoride
Measure nitrites
and nitrates
directly


Measure fluoride
directly
Industrial discharges
and agricultural
runoff
Fluoride is naturally
occurring in water.
(However this level may
be increased by addi-
tional fluorides  in the
atmosphere (such as
from gaseous industrial
wastes) acting to in-
crease the fluoride level
of rain or precipitation)

-------
Health impacts
  (Damages)

Amoebic dysentery
- acute effects
(even death)

Kidney stones
Method of Transmission
(1-b)  Water supply
(la) Water supply
    Pollutants
Endornebia histolytic
cysts
Dissolved solids
Indicator (Water
Quality Variable)

Coliform count
Dissolved solids
                                                                           Source of Pollutant
                                                                           Human feces
Industrial discharges
irrigation return
flows
 Coronary heart
 disease and
 cardiovascular
 disease
(la) Water supply
Hardness of the
water
Ha rdne s s of the
water
Naturally occurring
plus industrial
pollution
  oo

-------
Health impacts
  (Damages)  _

Offensive tastes
and odor - both
an esthetic and
toxicological
effect may result
from the sub-
stances
Method of Transmission
(1) Water supply
    Pollutants
Insecticides and organic
compounds (for ex.
phenols)
Indicator (Water
Quality Variable)

Taster-panels are
used and analytical
isolation techniques,
that have been con-
sidered for taste-
and-odor study of
water include dis-
tillation and a car-
bon adsorption
method
Source of Pollutant	

Insecticides from agri-
cultural sources and trace
trace organics and
chemical compounds
(from industrial dis-
charges ?)
sO

-------
Possible Procedures and Data Sources

       In order to evaluate adequately the major health impacts
(and the costs) associated with water quality degradation in the
United States, the following tasks will have to be completed:

       1.  Data concerning the incidence,  location, morbidity
           and mortality rates of the major diseases which are
           believed to be related to water quality will be col-
           lected from health statistics published  by the Public
           Health Service and other  sources. Representative
           sources  of data on water-related  diseases are:

           (a)  Morbidity and Mortality; Weekly Report, Center
                for Disease Control, Atlanta, Ga.  , U.S.D.H.E.W.
                Vol.  20, No.  53,  Annual Supplement, Summary, 1971.

                This is the most recent yearly summary in a series .
                It gives the reported incidence of notifiable diseases
                in the United  States for  1962-1971,  the deaths from
                specified notifiable diseases for 1959-1968 and
                deaths from selected non-notifiable acute diseases
               for 1959-1968.  Cases of diseases  are also reported
               by month and  by geographic region and state.

           (b)  Morbidity and Mortality^ Weekly Report, Center for
               Disease Control, Atlanta, Ga. , U.S.D.H.E.W., Vol.
               21, No. 42 (for week ending October 21, 1972).

               This  is a weekly report which can be used to obtain
               current data on incidence of notifiable diseases.

           (c)  Weibel, S.R., Dixon, F.R.,  Weidner, R.B. and
               McCabe,  L.J.  Waterborne-Disease Outbreaks,
                1946-1960,  Journal of the American Water Works
               Assoc.,  56,  947,  (1964)                    ~

           (d)  Hepatitis Surveillance, Report No.  19, Communicable
               Disease Center, June 30,  1964.

           (e)  Shigella Surveillance, Report No. 26, Center for
               Disease Control, April, 1971.
                            170

-------
2.  Methods of assessing the incidence of various diseases
    over time as related to specific water quality variables
    must be developed.

    (a) Plots of the number of cases of these water-related
        diseases vs time may be constructed to show trends
        in  such diseases over a time period (perhaps the last
        ten years),

    (b) Plots of appropriate water quality variables (for
        example, the coliform count,  see below)  which are
        considered reliable indicators of specific disease-
        associated variables vs time will be constructed
        and then shown on the same graphs.  These  graphs
         can be done for specific locations  in the United States
        as  well as for the nation as a  whole.

    (c) Correlation or multiple regression analysis of
         incidence of diseases and water quality variables
         can be used to establish relationship between
         disease  incidence and water quality.  For example,
         the coliform count can be used as an indicator
         variable for diseases such as hepatitis.  As a first
         approximation the virus concentration may be
        assumed to be directly proportional to the coliform
         count.   This is the logical assumption to make in
         relating surface water quality to number of infectious
        hepatitis cases (7).

    (d)  Sources of water quality variable data which can be
         used are:

         (1) Storet, Storage and Retrieval  System for Water
             Duality Data,  Environmental Protection Agency,
             1972.

         (2) Water Resources Data for Kansas  (also available
             for other states, Part 2.  Water Quality Records,
             United States Department of the  Interior. Geolog-
             ical Survey, (1967).

         (3) Water Pollution Surveillance  System, Annual Com-
             pilation, Public Health Service,  D.H.E.W. , Volumes
             available for 1957-58 through 1962-63.

                      171

-------
        3,   Costs associated with specific water-related diseases
            will be estimated.  Both direct and indirect costs of
            illnesses will be considered.   These costs  include
            work-days lost, medical care  costs and such intangibles
            as pain and suffering and disruption of family life and
            goals.  Other considerations such as the economic cost
            of mortality rates associated with these diseases must
            also be included.  (See references 8 and 9). Estimates
            of marginal costs or damages will be made wherever
            appropriate data is presently available.   Where a strong
            correlation between a water quality variable and a spec-
            ific health effect is found, the health costs associated
            with that effect will be related to the specific water
            quality variable to obtain marginal costs.
Summa r y

       While there is substantial evidence relating to various diseases
and adverse health impacts in general, to drinking water quality,
many studies have indicated that many of these impact initiate  from
untreated groundwater or inadequate control of present treatment
strategies.  Exhibit B-4 presents the percentage distribution of
sources of water borne diseases in the United States, 1946-1960.
This summary would seem to indicate that proper surveillance of
present treatment strategies and perhaps  chlorination of currently
untreated sources is  the least cost treatment strategy.
                             172

-------
 Exhibit B-4.  Percentage distribution of sources of waterborne
            disease in the United States, 1946-60
Source

Untreated surface water
Untreated ground water
Contamination of reservoir or cistern
Contamination of collection or conduit
system
Inadequate control of treatment
Contamination of distribution system
Miscellaneous
Total
Outbreaks
Percent
9.6
41.7
1.3

3.1
15.4
16.7
12. Z
100.0
Cases
Percent
3.2
33.9
0.7

4.6
41.4
1Z.9
3.3
100.0
Source: The Nation's Water Resources^ United States Water
        Resources Council, Washington, D. C.,  1968.,  p.  5-4-1.
                            173

-------
                       References Cited
(1)  la Riviere,  J.W.M. :  American  ociety for Microbiology
    72nd annual meeting, April 25, 1972, Philadelphia,  Pa., American
    Microbiology Society News,  38, No. 10:536,  1972.

(2)  Weibel, S.R., Dixon, F.R., Weidner,  R.B. and McCabe, L.J.:
    Waterborne-disease outbreaks,  1946-1960,  Journal of the American
    Water Works Association, 56: 947-958, 1964~

(3)  Dee,  Norbert et al. : Environmental Evaluationjaystem for Water
    Resource Planning, Bureau  oj^ Reclamation, U.£3.  Dept.  of Interior.
    January,  1972.

(4)  Morbidity and Mortality Weekly Report, Center for Disease Control,
    Vol. 21, No.  31: p. 263-4.

(5)  Shigilla Surveillance,  Fourth quarter,  1970, Center for  Disease
    Control, Report No. 26, April,  1971.

(6)  Morbidity and Mortality, Weekly Report,  Center for Disease
    Control, p.  379, November  4,  1972.

(7)  Journal of Sanitary Engineering Division,  American Society
    of Civil Engineers,  96:121,  February,  1970.

(8)  Rice, Dorothy P.  Estimating the Cost of  Illness,  Health Economics
    Series No. 6, U.S.  Dept.  H.EW. , Public Health Service Publication
    No. 947-6,  May, 1966.

    This publication lists direct  costs of illnesses as expenditures
    for prevention,  treatment, detection, rehabilitation,  research,
    training and capital investment in medical facilities.  The in-
    direct costs include loss of output to the economy due to morbidity
    and mortality.  Estimating procedures for both types of costs
    are summarized in this book.

(9)  Acute  Conditions; Incidence  and Associated  Disability, United
    States-July 1969-June 1970, D.H.E.W. Publication No.  (HSM)
    73-1503,  National Center for Health Statistics,  Rockville, Md. ,
    August,  1972.
                              174

-------
                         APPENDIX C
                      Specific Pollutants
       The following material presents a partial listing of what
are considered to be the damaging pollutants.  An accurate assess-
ment and assignment of priorities  is, of course,  impossible with-
out a detailed assessment of the damage potential of each individual
pollutant.  The following  list of pollutants must,  therefore, be in-
terpreted as  rather subjective and includes only  some of the pollutants
listed in Appendix A.  Also included is the potential damage resulting
from these pollutants,  their most common source and the treatment
required for  their removal.
                Exhibit C-l.  Specific Pollutants


       I.   BOD,  DO,  and Coliform

       II.   Inorganic Phosphate (especially where lakes and
            reservoirs are being considered)

      III.   Inorganic Nitrogen

      IV.   Total Dissolved Solids

       V.   Turbidity,  pH

      VI.   Temperature

     VII.   Pesticides and Toxic Substances
                                175

-------
I.   Dissolved Oxygen, Biochemical Oxygen Demand, and Coliform.
    Count:

    (A)  Sources

           The most generally accepted single criterion of pollu-
    tion is the  dissolved oxygen (DO) content of the stream.  Under
    favorable nonpolluted conditions, this may approach the saturation
    value, or may even exceed saturation because of photosynthesis
    or oxygen  generation in the stream.

           The DO saturation value is  low;  it depends on temperature,
    and is only 14 mg/liter at the freezing point, less at usual stream
    temperatures.  This implies that the reserve of available DO, to
    take care of bio-oxidation of organic wastes, is  not great and is
    easily depleted.  Organic wastes are generally characterized in
    terms of their biochemical oxygen demand (BOD); BOD is a
    measure of the oxygen consumed during biological oxidation.
    If large quantities of organic wastes are discharged  into a
    stream,  the dissolved oxygen in the stream may be rapidly
    depleted.   These organic wastes  occur in large quantities
    in industrial, and municipal waste waters.

           Coliform organisms are present in large quantities in
    the feces and urine of warmblooded animals.  They are present
    in water because of discharges of inadequately treated sewage
    and because they reproduce when organic wastes are present
    in water.

           Soil aeration and oxygen availability is also a factor
    deterring plant growth if water having high BOD values is
    used although no specific information is available.

    (B) Damages

           Total depletion of DO lends to nuisance conditions,
    including fish kills, bad odors and offensive appearances;
    even partial depletion may cause fish kills and render the
    stream unfit for its natural life forms.

           Coliform counts in water samples, especially fecal
    coliform, provide a good indication of the level of potential
    water-borne pathogens  capable of infecting man. Diseases
    can be transmitted from water to man in a number of ways
    {see section on Health).

                             176

-------
     (C)  Treatment

            Biological purification is widely used for treatment
     of waste water containing dissolved organic matter.  There
     are two broad types of bio-oxidation equipment, trickling
     filters and activated sludge.  Additional treatment can be
     obtained with carbon adsorption (tertiary treatment).

            Chemical agents such as ozone, chlorine dioxide,
     and chlorine, which are capable of oxidative reaction with
     organic compound may cause disinfection by direct chemical
     degradation of fecal coliforms, virus and pathogenic bacteria.
II.   Inorganic Phosphate

     (A) Sources

            Prior to the development of synthetic detergents, most
     of the inorganic phosphate was contributed by human waste as
     a result of metabolic processes.  The average amount of phos-
     phorus released per person in the United States is considered
     to be about 1. 5 G/day.

            Many synthetic detergents  contain from 12 to 13  percent
     phosphorus or over 50 percent of polyphosphates.  It has been
     estimated from sales of polyphosphates to the  detergent industry
     that domestic sewage probably contains from two to three times
     as much inorganic phosphorus at the present time as it did before
     synthetic detergents became widely used.

            Farm animals,  poultry manures and agricultural runoffs
     also contribute some inorganic phosphate.

     (B) Damage Effects

            Phosphorus and nitrogen are both essential for the growth
     of algae.  Limitation in the amounts of these elements is usually
     the factor that  controls their rate of growth.  Where both nitrogen
     and phosphorus are plentiful, algal blooms occur which may pro-
     duce a variety  of nuisance conditions.  The critical level for phos-
     phorus has been established as  somewhere near 0.01 mg/1.
                            177

-------
            At concentration of complex phosphates of the order
     of 100 mg/1,  difficulties with coagulation are experienced.

     (C)  Treatment

            Inorganic phosphates can be removed by a number of
     methods.  Among them, chemical coagulation is the most
     common way of removing inorganic phosphates,  The function
     of chemical coagulation may be the removal of suspended
     solids by destabilization of colloids to increase the settling
     velocity of settleable material, or removal of soluble in-
     organic compounds,  such as phosphorus, by chemical pre-
     cipitation  or adsorption on chemical floe.  The inorganic
     coagulants commonly used in wastewater coagulation are
     aluminum salts such as aluminum sulfate (alnm), lime,  or
     iron salts such as ferric chloride.  Polymeric organic
     coagulants are also used either as primary coagulants or
     coagulant aids. More than 99 percent removal of phosphorus
     has been obtained and effluent qualities of 0.2 to 0.6 mg/1
     have been reported at South Lake Tahoe.
III.  Inorganic Nitrogen

     (A)  Sources

            Nitrogen compounds are released in human waste
     products.  Urine contains the nitrogen resulting from the
     metaolic breakdown of proteins.  Also the feces of animals
     contain appreciable amounts of unassimilated protein matter.
     The other sources  of nitrogen come from agricultural runoff
     and industrial wastes.
     (B)  Damages

            Nitrites and nitrates are dangerous to humans if taken
     in excess. It was reported first in 1945 that infants who drank
     water polluted with 140 mg per liter of nitrate-nitrogen and
     0.4 mg per liter  of nitrite-nitrogen showed signs of dangerous
                             178

-------
     blood changes (methemoglobinerrvia).   Experiments with min-
     nows indicate that water containing 50 mg per liter of sodium
     nitrite  is fatal to these fish in fourteen days.  High concentra-
     tions of nitrates in waste water effluent act as a fertilizer
     and stimulate the growth of planktonic organisms and water-
     growing weeds,   To a certain degree, this increase of plank-
     tonic growth with the accompanying development of fishfood
     organisms brings about an increase in fish production.  As
     mentioned previously,  "where both nitrogen and phosphorus
     are plentiful, alga blooms  occur which may produce  a variety
     of nuisance  conditions.

     (C)   Treatment

            Three principal methods for removal of nitrogen from
     wastewater are ammonia stripping, selective ion exchange,
     and microbial denitrification.  Of these,  ammonia stripping
     is by far the cheapest,  simplest, and easiest to control.
     Selective  ion exchange is a reliable method,  but'a fairly
     complex one, and, at the present stage of development,
     appears to be rather costly.  Microbial denitrification is
     inexpensive, but the process is difficult to sustain and control.

IV.  Dissolved Solids

     (A) Sources

            Dissolved solids are mainly inorganic salts.   The most
     important ones are chlorides, calcium and magnesium which
     are related to water hardness, and many other solutes.   In-
     organic salts arise from all sources--urban, industrial, agri-
     cultural,  and natural; however,  the largest portion comes from
     industrial sources, particularly crude petroleum production,
     the manufacture of soda ash and other chemicals. Unlike other
     types, these wastes are relatively stable and do not decompose,
     decay,  or dissipate.
                              179

-------
(B) Damages

       Water with total dissolved solids  (TDS) less than about
500 ing/liter are used by farmers without awareness  of any
salinity problem.  Also without dilution from precipitation
or an alternative supply,  water with TDS of about 5000 mg/
liter usually have little value for irrigation.  Within these
limits, the value of the water appears to decrease as the
salinity increases. Where water is to be used regularly
for the irrigation  of relatively impervious soil,  its value is
limited if the  TDS is in the range of 2000 mg/liter.   Drinking
water standards recommend that total dissolved solids not
exceed 500 mg/1 where other more suitable water supplies
are available.  The desired value is  less than 200  mg/liter.
High total dissolved solids are objectionable because  of
physiological effects and mineral taste.  High concentrations
of mineral salts, particularly sulfates  and chlorides, are
associated with corrosion damage in water systems and  in-
dustrial facilities.

       Scaling occurs when calcium or magnesium compounds
in the water (water hardness) precipitate and adhere to boiler
internal surfaces.  These hardness compounds become less
soluble as temperature increases, causing them to separate
from solution. This scaling causes damage to heat transfer
surface by decreasing the heat exchange  capability.   The re-
sult is overheating of tubes,  followed by  failure and equipment
damage.

(C) Treatment

       Hard waters are often softened by adding sufficient
quantities of lime and  soda ash to precipitate the calcium and
magnesium as calcium carbonate and magnesium hydroxide.
Ion exchange, veversis osmosis,  electrodialysis,  freezing,
distillation and other desalination processes are also used
for removing  dissolved solids.  These processes are rela-
tively expensive.
                         180

-------
V.  Turbidity and pH

    (A)  Sources

            The term turbid is applied to waters containing suspended
    matter that interferes with the passage of light through the water
    or in which visual depth is  restricted.  The turbidity may be
    caused by a wide variety of suspended materials,  which range
    in size from colloidal to coarse dispersions, depending upon
    the degree of turbulence.  As rivers descend from mountain
    areas onto the plains, they receive contributions of turbidity
    from farming and other operations that disturb the soil.  Under
    flood conditions, great amounts of topsoil are washed to  re-
    ceiving streams.  Much of  this material is inorganic in nature
    but considerable amounts of organic matter are included.
    The domestic waste may add great quantities of organic and
    some inorganic materials that contribute turbidity.  Certain
    industrial wastes may add large amounts of organic substances
    and  other inorganic substances that produce turbidity.  Street
    washings contribute much inorganic  and some organic turbidity.

            Most of the acid or  alkali content comes from many
    industrial wastes.

    (B)  Damage

            Any turbidity in the drinking water is automatically
    associated with increased filtration in industrial and municipal
    preuse treatment processes.

            Filtration of water  is rendered more difficult and costly
    when turbidity increases.  The use of slow sand filters has be-
    come impractical in most areas because high turbidity shortens
    filter runs and increases cleaning costs. In turbid waters,
    most of the harmful organisms are exposed to the action of
    the disinfectant. However, in cases  in which turbidity is
    caused by sewage solids, many of the pathogenic  organisms
    maybe encased in the particles  and protected from the disin-
    fectants.  For this and aesthetic  reasons the United States
    Public Health Service has placed a limit of five units of tur-
    bidity as the maximum amount allowable in public water supplies,
                            181

-------
       In addition to increased municipal and industrial
costs turbidity further reduces the esthetic value of streams
and lakes.
       Either a high or a low pH maybe damaging,  causing fish
kills and general sterility in natural streams, and inactivating
the essential microorganisms  in sewage treatment processes.
Waste of low pH are  corrosive to steel and concrete structures
in waterways or sewage systems.

       The lacrimal fluid of the human eye has a  normal pH of
approximately 7.4 and a very high buffering capacity,  due
primarily to the presence  of buffering agents of the complex
organic type.  As  is true of many organic buffering agents,
those of the lacrimal fluid are able to maintain the pH within
a very narrow range until their buffering capacity is exhausted.
When the lacrimal fluid, through exhaustion of its buffering
capacity,  is unable to adjust the immediate contact layers of
the fluid to a pH of 7.4, eye irritation results.  A deviation
of no more than 0. 1 unit from the normal pH of the eye
may result in discomfort.   Appreciable deviation will  cause
severe pain.

(C)  Treatment

       Inorganic and organic colloidal suspensions in  water
can be removed by chemical coagulation. The coagulation
process, as practiced in waste water treatment,  involved
destabilization of the colloidal suspension follwed by f loc -
culation to generate large  particles which can subsequently
be removed either by sedimentation, flotation, or filtration.

       To eliminate the extremes  of pH in wastewaters usual
chemical neutralization is applied.
                        182

-------
VI.  Temperature

     (A) Sources

            While the contribution of heat from solar radiation
     is important,  the primary interest of the regulatory agencies
     is with heat added to the environment from industrial pro-
     cesses.  Although the most significant source of thermal
     pollution is steam-electrical generating activities,  it should
     be noted that the process industries which withdraw water
     for cooling purposes also contribute waste heat to the environ-
     ment.  The amount of fresh water required for  cooling con-
     densers is estimated to  increase from the 1955 usage of 60
     billion gallons a day to 200 billion gallons -- one-sixth of the
     freshwater in the United States--by 1988.  This heat can often
     be discharged either to the atmosphere or to water.

     (B) Benefits and Damages

            Temperature is one of the single most important factors
     controlling the distribution and  survival of aquatic organisms.
     Temperature increase s  affect fish directly by changing
     physiological and behavioral processes,  and indirectly by
     changing some  aspect of the environment on which  fish de-
     pend.  Mayer (1914) suggested  that high  temperatures pro-
     duced death in cold blooded animals by causing asphyxiation,
     the oxygen being insufficient to sustain the increased metabolic
     activity.   Sudden  changes in stream temperature,  such as  occur
     because of a plant shut down in winter can also cause fish kills
     and other damages.

             Some heating of  streams and rivers  can be  beneficial.
     Fish  grow faster  at warmer temperatures.  Melting of ice
     on rivers can sometimes be desirable.   Excessively high
     temperature may lessen the pleasure of  some water contact
     sports, as well as be  damaging to biota.  It has been determined
     that a person swimming expends energy  at the  rate of approxi-
     mately 500 calories per hour.  This energy must be dissipated
     to the environment to  avoid a rise in the deep body temperature.
     When conduction is  the principal means of heat transfer from
     the body and exposure to the environmental conditions is pro-
     longed, 90° F is the approximate limit for persons expending
     minimal energy.  High water temperature also reduces the
     cooling efficiency of water used as industrial coolants.
                                183

-------
      (C)  Treatment

             Thermal pollution of streams can be prevented by dig'
      charging the waste heat elsewhere.  Small man-made lakes
      can sometimes be used where water cooling is economically
      desirable.
VII.  Pesticides

     (A)  Sources

             Pesticides are materials used to prevent,  destroy,
     repel, or otherwise control objectionable insects, rodents,
     plants, weeds, or other undesirable forms of life. Pesti-
     cides may gain access  to ground and surface water supplies
     through percolation and runoff from treated areas.

     (B)  Damages

             Some pesticides are toxic to fish and other aquatic
     life  at only a small fraction of a mg/1.   Laboratory tests show
     that many coastal fisheries are especially sensitive to the
     toxic effects of low levels of pesticides.  Oysters, for example,
     will exist in the presence of DDT at levels as high as 0. 1 mg/1
     in the environment.  But at levels 1000  times less (0. 1 mg/1)
     oyster growth or production would be only 20 percent of normal,
     shrimp population would suffer a 20-percent mortality,  and
     menhaden would suffer a disastrous mortality.  They also tend
     to concentrate in aquatic plants and animals  to values several
     thousand times that occurring in the water in which they live.
     Also,  some pesticides  are  quite resistant to biological  degra-
     dation and persist in soils and water for long periods of time.

     (C)  Treatment

             The presence of pesticides is difficult to handle.  The
     best way is to avoid them rather than to remove them.
                              184

-------
                       APPENDIX D
           Critical Levels and Damage Thresholds
       Many aspects of water quality management must proceed
by disaggregating the problem into manageable proportions.  When
assessing the costs of pollution  one must consider a variety of indi-
vidual water quality constituents.   For this reason there is value
in presenting a variety of critical levels and damage thresholds by
beneficial uses.  The following tables  present a number of estab-
lished water quality guidelines and standards that have been adopted,
                            185

-------
Exhibit D-l.  Guide for Evaluating the Quality of Water Used for
                         Contact Recreation
  Quality factor	Limiting Concentration

  Fecal Coliform,  MPN per 100 ml                  200
      Range of pH                                 6. 5 - 8.3
      Temperature, maximum  (°C)                   30
      Clarity                                 A secchi disc is visible at a
                                             minimum depth of 4 feet
      Flotable oil and  grease, mg/liter                5
      Emulsified oil and grease, mg/liter             20
      Suspended solids,  mg/liter                    100
      Threshold odor number                        256
   Source:  Report of the Committee on Water Quality Criteria, Federal
            Water Pollution Control Administration, U. S. Department of
            the Interior, p. 4.
                                  186

-------
Exhibit D-2.   Guide for Evaluating the Quality of Water Used for General
                   Recreation (Boating and Esthetic)
   Quality factor                              Limiting Concentration

   Fecal coliform, MPN per  100 ml
      Range of pH                                6
   Total dissolved solids  (TDS), mg/liter
      Dissolved oxygen,  minimum mg/liter
      Carbon dioxide,  mg/liter
      Turbidity, JN
      Phosphorus,  mg/liter                     )      100   (flowing stream)
                                                           (lakes or reservoirs
      Flotable oil and  grease,  mg/liter
      Emulsified  oil and grease, mg/liter
      Threshold odor number
                                 187

-------
Exhibit D-3.  Guide for Evaluating the Quality of Water Used for
                         Marine and Estuarine
   Quality Factor
Limiting Concentration
   Salinity change, maximu,  %
      Range of pH
      Temperature change, maximum

      Dissolved oxygen, mg/liter
       ± 10
     6.7 - 8.5
       1.5- summer
       4   - fall,  spring and winter
       5
                                 188

-------
                       Exhibit D-4
              DRINKING WATER STANDARDS
Substance
Preferable Limits    Rejection Limits
Coliforms, MPN
Fecal colifortns, MPN
   Arsenic, mg/1
   Barium   "
   Boron     "
   Cadmium  "
   Chloride  "
   Chromium (hexavalent)
   Copper         "
   Iron           "
   Manganese     "
   Lead           "
   Nitrate         "
   Selenium       "
   Silver          "
   Sulfate         "
Total Dissolved Solids
   Zinc           "
   Cyanide        "
   Phenols        "
   Turbidity, units
   Color, units
   Odor (threshold odor number)
   Taste
      0.01
    250
      1.0
      0.3
      0.05
     45
    250
    500
      5
      0.01
      0.001

      USPHS

      5
     15
      3
1
1
0.05
1.0
0.01
0.01

0.05
0.05

0.01
0.05
0.2
                                                       AWWA Goals
No odor
None objectionable
                             189

-------
                                                        Exhibit D-5
                    Summary of Specific Quality Characteristics of Surface Waters That Have Been Used as Sources for
                                                     Industrial Water Supplies
(Unless otherwise indicated, units are mg/l
Boiler makeup water
Characteristic
Silica (SiO,) — 	
Aluminum (Al) 	 	 	
Iron (Fe)
Manganese 
-------
       Exhibit  D-6.   Guides for evaluating recreational waters
Determination
Coliforms, MPN per 100 ml
Visible solids of sewage origin
ABS (detergent), mg/liter
Suspended solids, mg/liter
Flotable oil and grease, mg/liter
Emulsified oil and grease, mg/liter
Turbidity , silica scale units
Color, standard cobalt scale units
Threshold odor number
Range of pH
Temperature, maximum °C
Transparency, Secchi disk, ft
Water contact
Noticeable
threshold
1000*
None
1*
20*
0
10*
10'
15*
32*
6.5-9.0
30
. . ,

Limiting
threshold
t
None
2
100
5
20
50
100
256
6.0-10.0
50
. . .
Boating and
Noticeable
threshold

None
1*
20'
0
20*
20*
15*
32*
6.5-9.0
30
20*
aesthetic
Limiting
threshold

None
5
100
10
50
t
100
256
6.0-10.0
50
t
   'Value not to be exceeded in more than 20 percent of 20 consecutive samples, nor in any 3 consecutive sample*.
   tNo limiting concentration can be specified in the basis of epidemiologies) evidence, provided no fecal pollution
I* evident. (Note: Noticeable threshold represents the level at which people begin to notice and perhaps to complain.
Limiting threshold is the level at which recreational use of water is prohibited or seriously impaired.
   INo concentration likely to be found in surface waters would impede use.
     Source:  California State Water Control Board,  1963
                                              191

-------
          Exhibit D-7.   Guides  for evaluating the quality of water
                                    used by  livestock
                  factor                                 Threshold                          Limiting
	tactof	concentration'	concentration!
Total dissolved solids (TDS), mg/liter                             2500                             5000
Cadmium, mg/liter                                               5
Calcium, mg/liter                                              500                             1000
Magnesium, mg/liter                                           250                              500:):
Sodium, mg/liter                                             1000                             2000J
Arsenic, mg/liter                                                1
Bicarbonate, mg/liter                                           500                              500
Chloride, mg/liter                                             1500                             3000
Fluoride, mg/liter                                                1                                6
Nitrate, mg/liter                                               200                              400
Nitrite, mg/liter                                              None                             None
Sulfate, mg/liter                                               500                             1000J
Range of pH	6.0-8.5	5.6-9.0
   •Threshold values represent concentrations at which poultry or sensitive animals might show slight effects from
prolonged use of such water.  Lower concentrations are of little or no concern.
   TLimitlng concentrations based on interim criteria. South Africa. Animals in lactation or production might show
definite adverse reactions.
   tTotal magnesium compounds plus sodium sulfate should not exceed 50 percent of the total dissolved solids.
    Source:  California  State Water  Quality Control Board,   1963
                                             192

-------
     Exhibit D-8.  Quality standards for water used for livestock
  	•  Threshold Salinity Concentration, ppm.
Poultry	   2,860
Pips	   4,290
Horses	   6,435
Cattle, dairy	   7,150
Cattle, beef	  .  10,000
Adult dry sheep	7%. . . .	•  •  12,900	
     Source:  Jour, of Agriculture  of Western Australia,  1950
                                       193

-------
           Exhibit D-9.   Limits  of Boron in irrigation water
A. Permissible Limits
   [Boron in parts per million]
Class of water
Excellent
Good
Permissible
Doubtful
Unsuitable

Sensitive
<0.33
0.33 to 0.67
0.67 to 1.00
1 .00 to 1 .25
> 1.25
Crop Group
Semitolerant
<0.67
0.67 to 1 .33
1.33 to?. 00
2.00 to 2.50
> 2.50

Tolerant
<1.00
1 .00 to 2.00
2. 00 to 3.00
3.00 to 3.75
> 3.75
B. Crop Groups of Boron Tolerance
  [In each group, the plants first named are considered as being more tolerant; the last named, more sensitive.]
Sensitive
Pecan
Walnut (Black; and Persian, or
English)
Jerusalem-artichoke
Navy bean
American elm
Ptum
Pear
Apple
Grape (Sultanina and Malaga)
Kadota fig
Persimmon
Cherry
Peach
Apricot
Thornless blackberry
Orange
Avocado
Grapefruit
Lemon
Semitolerant
Sunflower (native)
Potato
Cotton (Acala and Pi ma)
Tomato
Sweetpea
Radish
Field pea
Ragged Robin rose
Olive
Barley
Wheat
Corn
Milo
Oat
Zinnia
Pumpkm
Bell pepper
Sweet potato
Lima bean

Tolerant
Athel (Tamarix aphyllaf
Asparagus
Palm (Phoenix canarientis)
Date palm (P. dacty literal
Sugar beet
Mangel
Garden beet
Alfalfa
Gladiolus
Broadbean
Onion
Turnip
Cabbage
Lettuce
Carrot





   Source:  U. S. Department of Agriculture
                                      194

-------
     Exhibit  D-10.
Guides  for evaluating the quality of water
       used for irrigation
   [MPN is most probable number.  Sodium adsorption ratio is defined by the formula SAR=Na/V(Ca+Mg)/2 where the
   concentrations are expressed in milliequivalents per liter.  Residual sodium carbonate is the sum of the equivalents
   of normal carbonate and bicarbonate minus the sum of the equivalents of calcium and magnesium.)
                      Quality factor
                                Threshold
                             concentration*
   Limiting
concentrationt
Coliform organisms, MPN per 100 ml
Total dissolved solids (TDS), mg/liter
Electrical conductivity, ^mhos/cm
Range of pH
Sodium adsorption ratio (SAR)
Residual sodium carbonate (RSC), meq
Arsenic, mg/liter
Boron, mg/liter
Chloride, mg/liter
Sulfate, mg/liter
Copper, mg/liter
                                 1000*
                                  500J
                                  750$
                                 7.0-8.5
                                    6.0*
                                    1.25*
                                    1.0
                                    0.51
                                  100$
                                  200J
                                    0.11
        §
    1500|
    2250*
    6.0-9.0
      15
       2.5
       5.0
       2.0
     350
    1000
       1.0
   'Threshold values at which irrigator might become concerned about water quality and might consider using additional
water for leaching.  Below these values, water should be satisfactory for almost all crops and almost any arable soil.

   tUmiting values at which the yield of high-value crops might be reduced drastically, or at which an irrigator might be
'orced to less valuable crops.
   t Values not to be exceeded more than 20 percent of any 20 consecutive samples, nor in any 3 consecutive samples.
Th« frequency of sampling should be specified.

   § Aside from fruits and vegetables which are likely to be eaten raw, no limits can be specified. For such crops, the
  reshold concentration would be limiting.
   Source:  Calif.  State Water Quality Control Board,  1963
                                            195

-------
        Exhibit D-ll,
Guides for  evaluating  the quality of water
      for aquatic  life
                                                                    Threshold concentration*
Determination
Total dissolved solid* (TDS), mg/liter
Electrical conductivity, ^mhos/cm @ 25 C
Temperature, maximum °C
Maximum for salmonoid fish
Range of pH
Dissolved oxygen (D.O.), minimum mg/liter
Fiottble oil and grease, mg/liter
Emulsified oil and grease, mg/liter
Detergent, ABS, mg/liter
Ammonia (free), mg/liter
Arsenic, mg/liter
Barium, mg/liter
Cadmium, mg/liter
Carbon dioxide (free), mg/liter
Chlorine (free), mg/liter
Chromium, hexavalent, mg/liter
Copper, mg/liter
Cyanide, mg/liter
Fluoride, mg/liter
Lead, mg/liter
Mercury, mg/liter
Nickel, mg/liter
Phenolic compounds, as phenol, mg/liter
Silver, mg/llter
Sulfide, dissolved, mg/liter
Zinc, mg/llter
Freshwater
2000t
3000 1
34
23
6.5-8.5
6. Of
0
10T
2.0
0.5 1
LOT
S.OT
0.01 T
1.0
0.02
0.05T
0.02T
0.02T
1.5T
0.1 T
0.01
o.ost
1.0
0.01
0.5t
0.1
Saltwater


34
23
6.5-9.0
5.0:):
OT
10T
2.0

LOT




O.OST
0.02 T
0.02T
1.5T
O.IT
0.01


0.01
0.5T

   •Threshold concentration is value that normally might not be deleterious to fish life.  Waters that do not exceed these
values should be suitable habitats for mixed fauna and flora.
   tValues not to be exceeded more than 20 percent of any 20 consecutive samples, nor in any 3 consecutive samples.
Other values should never be exceeded.  Frequency of sampling should be specified.
   ^Dissolved oxygen concentrations should not fall  below 5.0 mg/liter more than 20 percent of the time and never below
2.0 mg/liter.  (Note: Recent data indicate also that rate of change of oxygen tension is an important factor, and that diurnal
changes In D.O. may, in sewage-polluted water, render the value of 5.0 of questionable merit.)
    Source:  Calif.  State Water Quality Control Board,  1963
                                            196

-------
Exhibit D-12.  Observed lethal concentration of selected
            chemicals in aquatic environments
Chemical
ABS (100 percent)
A8S (100 percent)
Household syndets
Alkyl sulfate
LAS (C 12)
LAS (C14)
Acetic acid
Alum
Ammonia
Ammonia
Sodium arsenite
Sodium arsenate
Barium chloride
Barium chloride
Cadmium chloride
Cadmium nitrate
CO,
CO
Chloramine
Chlorine
Chromic acid
Copper sulfate
Copper nitrate
Cyanogen chloride
H,S
HCt
HCI
Lead nitrate

Mercuric chloride
Nickel nitrate
Nitric acid
Oxygen
Phenol
Phenol
Potassium chromate
Potassium cyanide
Sodium cyanide
Silver nitrate
Sodium fluoride
Sodium sulfide
Zinc sulfate
Zinc sulfate
Pesticides
1 . Chlorinated hydrocarbons
A Aldrin
DDT
DDT
DDT
DDT
DDT
DDT
BHC
BHC
Chlordane
Chlordane
Dieldrin
Dieldrin
Oieldr.-1
Organism tested
Fathead minnow
Bluegitls
Fathead minnow
Fathead minnow
Bluegill fingerlings
Bluegill fingerlings
Goldfish
Goldfish
Goldfish
Perch, roach, 1
rainbow trout )
Minnow
Minnow
Goldfish
Salmon
Goldfish
Goldfish
Various species
Various species
Brown trout fry
Rainbow trout
Goldfish
Stickleback
Stickleback
Goldfish
Goldfish
Stickleback
Goldfish
Minnow, stickleback, (
brown trout )
Stickleback
Stickleback
Minnow
Rainbow trout
Rainbow trout
Perch
Rainbow trout
Rainbow trout
Stickleback
Stickleback
Goldfish
Brown trout
Stickleback
Rainbow trout


Goldfish
Goldfish
Rainbow trout
Salmon
Brook trout
Minnow, guppy
Stoneflies ( species)
Goldfish
Rainbow trout
Goldfish
Rainbow trout
Goldfish
Bluegill
Rainbow trout
Lethal concentration, mg/liter
3.5-4.5
4.2^.4
39-61
5.1-5.9
3
0.6
423
100
2-2.5 NH,
3N
17.8 As
234 As
5000
158
0.017
0.3 Cd
100-200
1 5
0.06
0.03-0.08
200
0.03 Cu
0.02 Cu
1
10
pHA.8
PH4.0
0.33 Pb

0.01 Hg
1 Ni
pH 5.0
3 cc/liter
6
9
75
0.13 Cn
1.04Cn
70 K
1000
15
0.3 Zn
0.5


0.028
0.027
0.5-0.32
0.08
0.032
0.75 ppb
0.32-1.8
2.3
3
0.082
0.5
0.037
0.008
0.05
Exposure time, hr
96
96
96
96
96
96
20
12-96
24-96
2-20
36
15
12-17

9-18
190
. . .
MO
. . .

60-84
160
192
6-48
96
240
4-6
• • •

204
156
. . .
. . .
3
1
60
2
2
154
60-102
. . .
120
64


96
96
24-36
36
36
29
96
96
96
96
24
96
96
24 __
                           197

-------
                   Exhibit D-12 (continued)
Chemical
Endrin
Endrin
Endrin
Endrin
Endrin
Heptachlor
Heptachlor
Heptachlor
Heptachlor
Methoxychlor
Methoxychlor
Toxaphene
Toxaphene
Toxaphene
Toxaphene
Toxaphene
Toxaphene
2. Organic phosphates
Chlorothion
Dipterex
EPN
Guthion
Guthion
Malathion
Parathion
TEPP
3. Herbicides
Weedex
Weeda Zol
Weeda Zol T.L.
Simazine
(no plants present)
Atrazine (A361)
(plants present)
Atrazine in Gesaprime
4. Baciericides
Algibiol
Soricide tetraminol
Organism tested
Goldfish
Carp
Fathead minnow
Various species
Stoneflies (species)
Rainbow trout
Goldfish
Bluegill
Redear sun fish
Rainbow trout
Goldfish
Rainbow trout
Goldfish
Carp
Goldfish
Goldfish
Minnows

Fathead minnow
Fathead minnow
Cathead minnow
Fathead minnow
Bluegill
Fathead minnow
Fathead minnow
Fathead minnow

Young roach )
and trench }
Minnow

Minnow

Minnow

Minnow
Minnow
Lethal concentration, mg/iiter
0.0019
0.14
0.001
0.03-0.05 ppb
0.32-2.4 ppb
0.25
0.23
0.019
0.017
0.05
0.056
0.05
0.0056
0.1
0.2
0.04
0.2

3.2
180
0.2
0.093
0.005
12.5
1.4-2.7
1.7

40-80
15-30
20-40
0.5

5.0

3.75

20
8
Exposuretime.hr
96
48
96

96
24
96
96
96
24
96
24
96

24
170
24

96
96
96
96
96
96
96
96

1 month
1 month
1 month
< 3 days

24

24

24
48
Source:  McGauhey, Engineering Management of Water Quality,
         McGraw-Hill, copyright 1968
                              198
                                           GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE: 1973-546-3l2/l->3 1-3

-------
SELECTED WATER
RESOURCES ABSTRACTS
INPUT TRANSACTION FORM
  I. RepotitfK
2.
                      w
   RESEARCH NEEDS AND  PRIORITIES:
   WATER POLLUTION  CONTROL  BENEFITS  AND COSTS VOL.  II
    "! David L. Jordening  and  James  K.  Allwood
     Development Planning and Research Associates
     200 Research Drive
     Manhattan, Kansas 66502
         ifit Orgsni • itioa '        •' '  ' "'* * .' ''
                      J.  Report Date
                      6.  '     -',-•-
                      t.
                                                                  21-AQJ-05
                        68-01-0744
                      g.  Type Sf Report and
                       '  Period Covered
     Environmental Protection Agency report number,
     EPA-600/5-73-008b, October 1973.
        This report  includes  foremost  a specification of research needs and priori-
   ties Involving water  pollution control costs and benefits.  A series of theoretic-
   al and methodological research needs are presented.  Water quality management is
   required  in  a dynamic setting and over a broad range of hydrologic and economic
   conditions.  The  common property resource aspects of the problem with the preval-
   ence of externalities complicates the issues involved.  These and other factors
   embedded  in  the research needs are discussed.  A major development of a cost-
   minimization methodological  approach for water quality management is also presented.
   Within this  framework the  indicated research needs are more readily identified
   and explained.  An important distinction is made between the economic costs of
    ollution and the costs of pollution abatement.  The economic costs of pollution
   such as damages,  efficiency reductions, increased production expenses, process
   changes and  opportunity costs are a function of water quality, whereas pollution
   abatement costs are typically a function of the degree of pollution control.  For
   comparable cost comparisons, a transformation of pollution abatement costs in
   terms of  water quality is  desired.   This transformation need and problem is dis-
   cussed in detail.  Finally,  in a series of technical appendicies, the following
   subjects  are discussed:  (1) water pollution control cost and benefit estimates,
   (2) water quality associated health impacts.
//a. Descriptors


   Water quality, Benefits, Costs, Benefit-Cost Analysis, Bibliographies, Literature,

   Economics

17b. Identifiers
   CO WKR fit-Id <£
                                                    Stad To:

                                                    WATER RESOURCES SCIENTIFIC INFORMATION CENTER
                                                    U.S. DEPARTMENT OF THE INTERIOR       <-tnTER
                                                    WASHINGTON. O C 2O24O
         Bernadette F.  Freeman
i-:n Environmental Protection Agency

-------