The Macroeconomic Impacts
of Federal Pollution Control Programs

-------
                                              11532
      The Macroeconomic  Impacts
of Federal Pollution  Control Programs
                  by
  Chase Econometric Associates, Inc.
      Bala Cynwyd,  Pennsylvania
            undertaken for
 The Council on Environmental  Quality
 The Environmental Protection  Agency
             January 1975

-------
                    TABLE OF CONTENTS
Introduction                                         1




Principal Conclusions                                1




      Impact on Inflation                            1




      Impact on Economic Growth                      2




      Impact on Unemployment                         2




      Investment                                     2




Pollution Abatement Costs                            3




Methodology and Assumptions                          3




Operation of Model                                   7




Results of Analysis                                  g




      Impact on Prices                               9




      Impact on Economic Growth                      9




      Impact on Investment                          13




      Impact on Foreign Trade                       13




      Other Economic Impacts                        13




      Sensitivity Analyses                          14




Conclusion                                          16

-------
                        FOREWORD

      This analysis of the macroeconomic impact of pollution
control expenditures was sponsored by CEQ and EPA as part
of a continuing effort to assess the impact of environmental
programs on the economy.  Further studies on this issue are
expected to be released this year.

      The analysis is based upon CEQ/EPA estimates of "incre-
mental abatement costs" associated with current Federal air
and water pollution control legislation.  These costs are
defined as the public and private expenditures expected to
be made as a result of Federal environmental legislation
which would not have been made in the absence of this legis-
lation.  The methodology and data sources used in estimating
these costs are described in the fifth annual report of the
CEQ.*

      The cost estimates are primarily based on the
assumption that the deadlines and standards established in
the Clean Air Act  (as amended) and the Federal Water Pollution
Control Act  (as amended) will be achieved.  They, therefore,
show a significant peaking prior to 1978.  There is some
evidence that these deadlines will not all be met, and that
some expenditures will be delayed beyond 1978.  In this case
the macroeconomic effects of the programs would likely be
less than projected in these analyses.

      However, the cost estimates do not fully include the
costs associated with meeting the 1983 standards established
by the 1972  amendments to the Federal Water Pollution Control
Act, and therefore, the actual macroeconomic impacts at the
end of the decade  1973-82 may be greater than projected.  It
should also  be noted that the initial computer runs for this
study were made in the fall of 1974 and hence some of the
baseline forecasts do not completely reflect subsequent
changes in economic conditions.

      Further macroeconomic analyses of this type are expected
to be undertaken in the future as the abatement cost estimates
are changed.
                            Edwin H.  Clark, CEQ
                            Roy N. Gamse, EPA
                            January  1975

*The Council on Environmental Quality, Environmental Quality
 1974  (U.S. novernment Printing Office, 1974), Appendix 1 to
 Chapter 2.

-------
conometrics
                                   INTRODUCTION
      This  study represents  an updating  and  continuation of  the work done in
 previous years  by Chase Econometrics  for  the Environmental  Protection Agency
 (EPA) and  the Council  on Environmental  Quality (CEO)  in assessing  the macro-
 economic impact of Federal  environmental  programs.1   The  analysis  uses abate-
 ment  cost  estimates for the period  1973-1982 supplied by  EPA and CEQ for air
 and water  pollution abatement;  these  figures are given in Table  1.  The
 estimates  include capital investment, annualized capital  costs, and operating
 and maintenance costs  for each of the years in the period of analysis, and are
 disaggregated by two-digit  industry.  The cost estimates  are consistent with
 the "incremental abatement costs" estimates published in  the CEQ 1974  annual
 report.

      The analysis was  performed using the Chase Econometrics macroeconomic
 and input/output models, which are  linked together into a single solution
 algorithm.   The Chase  model system  thus allows analysis of  both  the impacts
 that  different  industries have on one another and on  the  interaction between
 pollution  control expenditures and  general  economic factors such as the rate
 of growth,  inflation,  unemployment, and financial markets.

      Most  of the analysis is based  upon the EPA/CEQ estimated  level and timing
 of costs superimposed  on a general  cyclical economic  scenario  taken from a
 recent Chase Econometrics ten-year  forecast.  The impacts of the pollution con-
 trol  expenditures are  estimated by  comparing the economic forecasts including
 these expenditures with a forecast  which  is similar in every respect except
 that  it  excludes such  additional environmental expenditures.   It should be
 noted, however, that the inclusion  of these expenditures  involves  several
 sets  of adjustments to the model, which are discussed in  greater detail in
 the Methodology and Assumptions section.  However, an additional 11 simulations
 were also  calculated using different  cost estimates,  alternative assumptions
 about the  underlying economic scenario, the level of  expenditures, and their.
 timing over the ten-year period. These alternative scenarios  are  discussed
 in more  detail  later in this report.
                               PRINCIPAL CONCLUSIONS

 Impact on Inflation

      By 1978,  when the bulk of the incremental investment in the industrial
 sector is complete, the wholesale price index will be 3.0% higher,  the implicit
 GNP deflator will be 1.9% higher, and the consumer price index will be 1.2%
 higher than would have been the case in the absence of pollution control  expen-
 ditures.   These correspond to an average annual rate of increase of 0.6%  for
 the WPI,  0.4% for the GNP deflator,  and 0.24% for the CPI over this period.
   The Economic Impacts of Meeting Exhaust Emission Standards,  1971-1980,
 October,  1971; The Economic Impact of Pollution Control  Upon the General
 Economy,  October, 1972; The Economic Impact of Pollution Control:   Macro-
 economic  and Industry Reports, July. 1973.

-------
conometrics
      In the latter half of the 1973-1982 decade the effect  on  prices  is  reduced.
 liy l<)82 the cumulative nricc different 1:1 Is arc only 2.'\%,  0.9%,  and 0.2°i.   This
 reduction in the price differentials results from a substantial  reduction  in
 investment and, in part, to the incremental slowdown in the economy.   Thus, when
 averaged over the decade, the WPI increases (}.2"« more,  the GNP deflator  0.1%
 more,  and tho CP1 0.021 more with pollution control expenditures.

      The largest single-year increments occur in 1976.  when the  WPI rises  1.8%
 more and the riNP deflator 0.91. more because of pollution control expenditures.
 Por the CPI. the largest single-year differential is in 1977,  when it rises
 O.c»?i more than it otherwise would have.

 Impact  on Lcononic Growth

      The stimulus of increased expenditures on pollution control growth  in the
 early years of the decade is projected to raise the rate of economic  growth
 above what it would have otherwise been through 1976.   The maximum differential
 in the  rate of growth occurs in 1975,  when constant dollar GNP will be 1.6%
 higher  with pollution control expenditures.  In the latter half  of the decade,
 however,  low levels of pollution control investment combined with a higher rate
 of inflation leads to slower economic  growth.   By 1979  real GNP  is projected  to
 be J.0"« below the baseline forecast.   This difference gradually  diminishes and
 by 1982 the real GNP ends up virtually the same in both forecasts.

 Impact  on Unemployment

      In keeping with the pattern of overall economic growth, the unemployment
 rate is (i.4°o lower in 1975 and O.Vi lower in 1976 than  it  otherwise would  have
 been.   However, it gradually rises to  a level  of 0.4% above the  baseline fore-
 cast by 1979.  The difference gradually decreases and returns  almost  to  zero
 by 1982.

 Investment
      The cost estimates provided by EPA/CEQ show incremental  pollution control
 investments amounting to approximately 5% of total  plant  and  equipment expendi-
 tures through 1976.   This investment is estimated to result in somewhat lower
 levels of other types of investment, the substitution taking  place approximately
 at  .-> r;itc of $0.40 reduction in all other private investment  for every $1.00 of
 investment in pollution control plant and equipment."  However,  the housing
 sector usually accounts for the majority of the reduced investment because of
 its greater sensitivity to the cost and availability of borrowed funds.   This
 impact dcncnds very much on the particular fiscal and monetary policy being
 pursued by the government.  The combined effects of slower economic growth,
 greater credit stringency, and the increased cost of capital  reduce annual
 investment in plant and equipment some 4.8% below the baseline level in 1979;
 this difference declines to 2.5*j by 1982.   Housing  starts decline by as much
 as  15.3". in 1978, although this difference disappears by  the  end of the fore-
 cast period.
 This  result  is  based  on a  number of simulations performed with the Chase
 Econometrics  macro model under different assumptions about underlying econo-
 mic conditions.

-------
                                         -3-

cohometrics

                             POLLUTION ABATEMENT COSTS

      The  cost  estimates used  in  this analysis arc consistent with the most
 recent  CI~Q  estimates of "incremental abatement costs" beinj- published in  its
 li)7<1  annual  report.  The CLQ  defines "incremental" abatement costs as expendi-
 tures made  to  satisfy  the  requirements  of  Federal environmental legislation
 beyond  what  would  have been  spent  for pollution control  in the absence of this
 legislation.   Some industries arc  shown to have negative  investment for air
 pollution in the years following 1978,  which means that  the firms in those
 industries  would h.ivc  undertaken certain investment  for  pollution control in
 any case, but  did  so sooner  because of  I-'cderal legislation.

      The  cost  estimates, which arc predominantly based upon cost estimator
 provided  in  the  1974 edition  of  The Cost of Clean Air and the  1975 edition
 of  The  Economics of Clean  Water, arc summarized in Table  1.  Those figures
 were  made available to Chase  Econometrics  for 15 two-digit industries in the
 manufacturing  sector,  utilities, and public sector investment.  Very small
 expenditures which were also  given for  agriculture and mining  were combined
 into  the  appropriate manufacturing category.  These  figures were given on an
 annual  b.isis for the years 1975  to 1982 and were separated into expenditures
 for .iir pollution  and  water  pollution abatement.  The estimates included
 investment  cost, annual operation  and maintenance costs,  and total annual costs.
 Annual  costs include depreciation, interest charges, and  operating and mainten-
 ance  expenditures.  In addition, figures were supplied for the cost of meeting
 mobile  source  emission standards for automobiles.

      In addition to the basic analysis  using the cost estimates summarized  in
 Table 1,  four other sensitivity analyses  were run using  different assumptions
 about the level or timing  of  costs.  The first of these  assumed that, on the
 average,  capital  investment  would  be 2()9« less than estimated,  but that opera-
 ting  and  maintenance costs would be  1 5°<> higher.  This adjustment was made to
 reflect the  impact of  an  increased emphasis on process changes rather th.m
 cnd-of-thc-pipe treatment  for pollution abatement.   The  EPA/CEQ cost estimates
 (predominantly) assume "end-of-thc-pipc" treatment.

      The  second cost sensitivity scenario  assumed that all costs were increased
 by  25"o  in order  to estimate  the  likely  macrocconoimc impact if the 1IPA/CKQ
 estimates were significantly  understated.  The third cost sensitivity scenario
 involved  an  "evening out"  of  costs over the ten-year period -- and a delay of
 some  costs  beyond  the  period  --  in order to determine the impact of a delay in
 implementing the  current  compliance  dates.  Finally, because of  the  sharp drop
 in  housing  starts  in  some  years, we  returned  the  level of housing activity  to
 its  baseline level in  order to determine what  the effect of this policy  might
 be  when applied in conjunction with  the pollution control  expenditures.
                           METHODOLOGY  AND  ASSUMPTIONS

      The  baseline values  for the  overall economic  scenario  arc  taken  from  the
 Chase Econometrics long-term macroeconomic outlook.  In  this  forecast we predict
 a  continuation of the  recession throughout 1974  and  a  rise  in the  rate of  unem-
 ployment  continuing  into  1975.  After  that,  the  economy  gradually  returns  to a
 4V«>  rate  of  unemployment  in  1978  and  remains at  that level  through 1980.   This
 baseline  projects another small business cycle from  1980 to 1983,  but the  unem-
 ployment  rate  returns  to  4%°* by 1985.  The indicated growth rate for  real  GNP

-------
TABLE 1
ESTIMATED INCRI.MF.NTAL POLI UTION CONTROL EXPENDITURES, 1973-1982
Air Pollution
Abatement Costs
1973-77
Investment Annual
1188
0
0
130
285
565
icts 0
0
195
2479
946
0
0
0
0
5786
8861
1314
15965
ols 10900
577
0
0
195
306
560
0
0
290
1424
1237
0
0
0
0
4589
10575
1701
16865
21150
Water Pollution
Abatement Costs
1973-77
Investment Annual
1448
417
545
974
1340
966
214
126
616
749
286
482
376
306
238
9083
1925
17900
28908

1665
48(.
964
760
860
702
399
143
231
257
224
253
210
145
103
7402
754
7990
16146

Air Pol Kit ion
Abatement Costs
1978-82
Investment Annual
-5h
0
0
-6
-14
-27
0
0
-9
-118
-45
0
0
0
0
-275
1867
407
1999
20370
504
0
0
227
338
611
0
0
336
1338
1412
0
0
0
0
4766
17440
2702
24908
53280
Water Pol hit ion
Abatement Costs
1978-82
Investment Annual
119
34
45
80
110
79
18
10
51
61
24
40
31
25
20
747
2476
-3150
75

2485
726
1466
1105
1228
1014
608
214
305
321
340
352
295
200
140
10797
2319
10868
23984

 Food  6  Kindred  Products
 Textiles
 Lumber
 Paper 6 Paper Products
 Chemicals
 Petroleum
 Rubber  & Misc.  Plastic Products
 Leather
 Stone,  Clay  5 Glass
 Iron  &  Steel
 Primary Nonferrous Metals
 Fabricated Metals
 Nonelectrical Machinery
 Electrical Machinery
 Transportation  Equipment
  Total Industrial
 Utilicies c
 Public
  Total Fixed Source
 Mobile Source emission controls
 a
  includes feedlots and grain handling
  includes coal  cleaning and natural gas production
  includes residential/commercial/industrial heating
All figures are in millions of 1973 dollars.
The definitions  of investment and annual costs  arc  given on page 3.

-------
                                         -5-

Sohometrics

 averages 4.0% for the period 1975-1980 and 3.7?0 for the  period  1981-1983.
 The rate of inflation as measured by the consumer price  index averages 6.5%
 from 1975 to 1980 and 5.2% from 1981 to 1983.

      Other major factors of the baseline forecast include the assumption  that
 both the Federal and state and local government budgets  will remain approxi-
 mately in balance over the coming decade,  with an average annual  surplus  of
 $3 billion over this period.  The personal savings rate  will average approxi-
 mately 7^% for the period, representing an increase from the postwar average
 of 6'i?o; this will be due primarily to a higher average rate of  inflation.
 New car sales will increase from a low level of 9.1 million units in 1974
 to 11.2 million in 1976 and then rise slowly from that point to 12.8 million
 units in 1983.  Housing starts will rebound from a low level of 1.4 million
 units this year to 1.9 million units in 1976 and will remain at approximately
 this level for the rest of the decade, but will not surpass the figure of
 2.05 million starts recorded in 1973.  Short-term interest rates will decline
 from present peak levels, but long-term interest rates will continue to  rise
 and will average approximately 11% over the decade.

      An alternative scenario, called the "full employment baseline" is not
 vastly different from the cyclical baseline.  The EPA/CEQ provided guidelines
 to Chase Econometrics which stated that the real growth  rate  should average
 4.6% per year for the 1975-80 period and 3.2% per year for the  1981-83 period.
 Furtnermore, it was stipulated that the unemployment rate should average  5.4%
 in 1975 and 3.9% in both 1980 and 1983.  We have maintained these conventions
 jn solving for the baseline full employment scenario. As we move to higher
 rates of employment, the rate of price increase is slightly larger.  Thus the
 consumer price index increases at a 6.7% annual rate during the forecast  period,
 compared to a 6.01 increase in the baseline forecast. Similarly, the implicit
 C".NP deflator rises at 6.5% instead of 5.8%,  and the wholesale price index rises
 ;it 5.8°; instead of 5.0%.  The model has been adjusted so that  real GNP  rises
 at .m average rate of 4.1% compared to 3.9% in the cyclical baseline case.
 Other variables arc not significantly affected; the personal  savings rate
 remains around 74% and housing starts average just under 2 million units  per
 year, although new passenger car sales rise about 1% a year faster.

      We now consider the major steps which were taken to enter  the GPA  pollution
 cost figures into the Chase Econometrics industry and macro models.  These can
 be briefly summarized as follows:
         1)  Enter the estimated investment costs for each industry into the
             model as an addition to the year by year demand for plant  and
             equipment investment.   These adjustments have two effects:
             (a) they are added directly to the investment functions in the
             model (see (7) below),  and (b) they increase the asset base on
             which firms must earn the normal rate of return, hence resulting
             in higher prices.

-------
                                  -6-
nometrics
       2)   [Enter  the  annual operation and maintenance costs and interest
           costs  on pollution control investments into the model as an
           increase in  each industry's production costs.

       3)   Apply  "markup"  factors  to the increase in production costs,
           including  capital depreciation,  interest charges, and operation
           and  maintenance, to determine the  increase in prices.  The markup
           factors, which  represent the proportion of increased costs passed
           along  as higher prices, have already been calculated on an indus-
           try  by industry basis in the Chase Econometrics industrial models.
           The  markups  in  general  range from  0.8 to 1.0.  A. markup factor of
           1.0  indicates that the  average firm in the industry will be able
           to just recover all the increased  costs through product prices.

       4)   Calculate  the effect which these price increases will have on all
           industries.  The previous step calculated only the direct effect
           of pollution controls on prices; that is, the amount that the price
           of steel (e.g.) rises because the  steel industry invests in pollu-
           tion control plant and  equipment.  However, we must also consider
           the  effects  which an increase in steel will have on machinery, autos,
           and  other  steel-using industries.  In other words, we must measure
           the  indirect as well as the direct effects of the price increases
           in each industry.

       5)   Convert the  price increases by final demand categories to price
           increases  by aggregate  demand categories.  We use a reverse bridge
           matrix to  go from the 40 categories of final demand to the aggre-
           gate demand  components  contained in the Chase Econometrics macro
           model.

       6)   Translate  the price increases which come from the input-output
           table  and  the bridge matrix -- as  given in (5) above -- into actual
           ex post price changes by using the markup factors at the macro level.
           Until  this has  been accomplished we do not yet know what changes  in
           final  product prices will be, since the cost increases may not be
           fully  passed along.  Thus we use the markup factors at the final
           demand level (consumption, investment, and exports) to determine
           what the price  rise will be before taking into account interactive
           and  dynamic  factors.  These markup factors range from 0.8 to 1.1.

       7)   Adjust for changes in fixed business investment due to pollution
           control expenditures.   Since more  investment will be needed, the
           constant terms  in the investment functions should be raised accord-
           ingly.  However, we adjust the rental cost of capital upward by the
           percentage of investment for pollution control because it will now
           take more  investment to produce  a  given amount of output.  Hence
           the  required rate of return on investment for capacity expansion
           will have  to increase to offset  the zero financial return on the
           pollution  control investments.

       8)   Labor  productivity was  adjusted  downward through a decrease in
           capital stock to reflect the fact  that the additional capital
           expenditures for pollution control do not increase output/manhour.

-------
                                      -7-

Sbhometrics

          9)  The  index of  industrial  production was increased to represent
             the  manufacture of auto  emission control devices.

         10)  The  consumption of transportation services was increased because
             of higher operating and  maintenance costs due to the catalytic
             converters and other pollution control devices.

         11)  Corporate profits were adjusted downward to tnkc into account
             the  added costs of pollution  control.  The existing profit
             functions would show an  increase in profits if prices rose and
             unit labor costs, raw material prices, interest rates, output,
             and  capacity  utilization all  stayed at the same level.

         12)  The  amount of financing  undertaken by the Federal government
             increased, reflecting higher  government debt because of increased
             spending in the public sector, and the amount of bond financing
             was  also increased by the amount necessary to keep the debt/equity
             ratio constant.

      A  final  round of price and output changes were then obtained by solving
  the  complete  Chase macroeconomic model, taking into account the interactive
  and  dynamic factors.


                             OPERATION OF  MODEL

      We now consider the  interactive and  dynamic features of the macroeconomic
  model.   The additional plant and equipment expenditures for pollution control
  will reduce the  amount of investment in the private sector undertaken for other
  purposes.  Part  of this effect has already been included by raising the value of
  the  rental cost  of capital term.3  However, several other factors need to be taken
  into account.  First, an  increase in nominal investment will place greater pressure
  on the  capital markets, thus  increasing interest rates and lowering other invest-
  ment.   Second, the increased  investment demand will cause an increase in the costs
  of construction  materials,  labor, and equipment which results in some decline in
  constant dollar  investment  for a given level of output and financial variables.
  Third,  .1 significant substitution exists  between residential and nonrcsitlenti.nl
  construction.  This substitution works through changes  in three variables:  credit
  nva i l.ihi 11 ty, the cost of construction, and the availability of labor.  Since
  housing is more  sensitive than other construction to all three of these variables,
  it suffers the greatc'st decline when other sectors of investment increase.  The
  average elasticity of substitution between pollution control expenditures and
  other  fixed investment  is approximately 0.4, .is has already been mentioned.  This
  value  can reach  even larger values during periods of overfull employment and strin-
  gent monetary policy, although it does not  in these simulations.
  3                                          I»K (r+6)  (1-uz-k)
  "The  rental  cost  of capital  is  defined  as   	~—j-.	r	  where

  P  =  supply  price of capital  goods       z   = depreciation  factor
  r  -  cost  of borrowed funds              J   = '"vestment  tax  credit rate
  r    ,                                   P.. = wholesale price index
  6  =  depreciation rate                  W            r
  u  =  marginal statuatory tax rate .

-------
                                         -8-

conometrics

      It  should  he  mentioned  that  a  higher  rate of  inflation leads to a slower
 rate  of  growth  in  the  economy  for a number of other  reasons.  The most impor-
 tant  link:   a rise in  the  rate of inflation  increases the savings rate and
 hence reduces consumption.   According  to the permanent income hypothesis, the
 marginal  propensity to consume is lower  for  variable incomes than it is for
 fixed incomes.   Yet clearly  inflation  penalizes  those on fixed incomes at the
 expense  of  those on variable incomes.  During inflation the decline in consump-
 tion  by  those on fixed incomes is not  nearly matched by the increase in con-
 sumption  by those  on variable  incomes  -- even if we  assume that income changes
 are the  same -- and thus the savings rate  rises.   This is one of the important
 endogenous  relationships in  the macro  model, and works through the income dis-
 tribution and relative price terms  in  the  consumption function.  In addition
 there is  a  relative decline  in durable purchases which is not balanced by the
 slightly  higher spending on  services.

      The  other  channels by which  a  rise  in prices  lowers real output are more
 straightforward and require  only  brief commentary.   First, for a given nominal
 money supply, higher prices  must  lead  to a lower real money supply and hence
 an increase in  interest rates  unless there has been  a specific offsetting
 shift in  the liquidity preference function;  this leads to the effects on invest-
 ment  which  have already been discussed.  Second, an  increase in domestic prices
 for a given level  of foreign prices leads  to a deterioration in the net  foreign
 balance  in  constant prices,  although if  the  sum  of the price elasticities of
 exports  and imports is less  than  unity,  the  balance  in nominal terms may increase.
 Third,  a government budget which  is fixed  in current dollars buys fewer  goods and
 services  and generates less  employment if  prices increase.  If the government
 attempts  to retain its real  purchasing power, it can do so only by creating
 ndditional  money,  which will in turn raise prices, or by borrowing additional
 funds,  which will  raise interest  rates.  We  have chosen to assume that this
 latter route is operative, as indicated  in our earlier discussion of constant
 adjustments.

      All  of these  linkages reinforce the result  that a rise in costs and prices
 will  reduce aggregate  demand and  raise unemployment.  As soon as this happens,
 however,  secondary effects which  act in  the  opposite direction begin to  surface.
 A rise in unemployment will  result  in  a  lower level  of wage increases in follow-
 ing years.   Thus unit  labor  costs and  prices will  not rise as much for a given
 increase in productivity.   In addition,  the  lower  level of capacity utilization
 leads to lower  markup  factors.  When these events  begin to  increase in impor-
 tance, the rate of price  increase starts to  diminish.  The decline in real
 GNP  and employment, which  was originally caused  by higher prices, also begins
 to slacken.  As this continues, prices and real  GNP  tend to return toward the
 level which would  have occurred  if  the additional  costs had not been added.
 Under a fairly  wide variety  of assumptions it is likely that  the economy will
 eventually return  to the  level of output and employment which would have
 occurred in the absence of expenditures  for  pollution control, although  prices
 will  remain somewhat higher  because of a lower  level of productivity.

-------
                                         -9-

bonometrics

                                 RESULTS OF AN'\LYSIS

 Impact on Prices

      The economic effects of pollution control expenditures are found to be
 rather modest.  By 1978 the implicit f.NP deflator is only 1.9% above the base-
 line case, the wholesale price index is only 3.0%, and the consumer price
 index only 1.2% above their baselines.   The biggest price effect occurs in
 1976, when the GNP deflator with pollution control costs rises 0.9% more than
 in the baseline scenario, and in 1977,  when it rises 0.6% more.  The difference
 in all other years is much less.   Similarly, the wholesale price index rises
 an additional 1.9% in 1976 because of pollution control expenditures.  This is
 the largest annual increase for any of the macroeconomic price indicators.

      The fact that some price increase does occur is no surprise, since it is
 .issumcd that pollution control expenditures do not increase output per unit of
 labor or capital.  The increased aggregate demand caused by the pollution con-
 trol expenditures with no compensating increase in aggregate production inevi-
 tably results in higher prices.  The amount of inflation will depend upon how
 much "slack" there is in the economy.  At "full employment", the price increases
 caused by the additional demand could be very significant, while a sluggish
 economy will result in less increase.  Even with a sluggish ecnnomv. however,
 there will be some price increase as firms pass on higher production costs in
 the form of higher prices, and as resources are competed away from other sectors
 to the production and installation of pollution control equipment.

 Impact on^ jjconomic Growth

      There has been a considerable amount of disagreement about whether pollution
 control expenditures on balance increase or diminish the rate of real growth and
 employment.  Some economists have argued that the additional expenditures asso-
 ciated with pollution control investment will result in a higher growth rate and
 hence .j higher level of employment.  Our results support this analysis for the
 pcrioil before 1977.  However, they also reveal that pollution controls contribute
 to the negative effect of higher inflation on real growth after  1977.  This  latter
 effect works through several different channels, which have already been described
 in the previous section.

      As .1 result, we have a somewhat variegated picture of an  incremental pattern
 ol" real growth over the forecast period.   During  the early years  --  1974  through
 l()7(i -- real GNP  is higher than the baseline  solution and hence  unemployment  is
 lower.  However,  in 1977 and succeeding years the picture is reversed.  First,
 less new investment is being added in  1977 and subsequent years.   Second, the
 additional price  increases resulting from  the environmental expenditures  set  in
 motion forces that lead to a slower rate of  real growth causing  real GNP  to  be
 lower and unemployment higher in the perturbed solution in the years 1977 through
 1982.  The greatest decrement in real  growth  is reached in  1979,  when the per-
 turbed real GNP  is 2.0% below the baseline solution.

      After  1979,  countervailing forces come  into place.  The  lower rate of growth
 leads to a higher rate of unemployment, which in  turn  leads to  smaller  increases
 in wage rates, unit labor costs and prices.   In addition, a decline  in  capacity

-------
                                                    TABLE  II
                                                1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
                                                                                               1980
1981
                                                       1982
Gross National  Product, Current  Dollars
   Baseline  projection
   With pollution  control costs
   % Difference

Gross National  Product, 1973 Dollars
   Baseline  projection
   With pollution  control costs
   % Difference

Implicit GNP Deflator. 1973 = 100
   Baseline  projection
   With pollution  control costs
   % Difference

-fonsumer Price  Index,  1973 = 100
   Baseline  projection
   With pollution  control costs
   % Difference

Wholesale Price Index. 1975 = 100
   Baseline  projection
   With pollution  control costs
   % Difference

Unemployment Rate, Percent
   Baseline  projection
   With pollution  control costs
   % Difference

Fixed Investment  in Producers Durable
Equipment,   1973 Dollars
  Baseline projection
  With pollution control  costs
  % Difference
1405.1
1413.8
.62
1279.5
1286.9
.58
109.8
109.8
.00
110.9
111.0
.09
121.0
121.1
.08
5.2
5.1
-1.92
91.4
93.8
2.63
1557.9
1586.8
1.86
1303.1
1323.4
1.56
119.5
119.9
.33
120.5
121.0
.41
135.5
136.3
.96
5.5
5.1
-7.27
95.7
102.4
7.00
1738.9
1779.1
2.31
1364.0
1379.0
1.10
127.5
129.0
1.18
128.6
129.4
.62
142.2
146.2
2.81
5.3
5.0
-5.66
102.8
107.4
4.47
1931.2
1962.0
1.59
1435.2
1432.5
-.19
134.5
136.9
1.78
136.4
138.0
1.17
148.7
153.5
3.23
4.8
4.8
.00
109.3
110.2
.82
2149.6
2157.7
.38
1514.0
1491.8
-1.47
141.9
144.6
1.90
144.6
146.4
1.24
155.8
160.5
3.02
4.4
4.6
4.S5
116.7
114.4
-1.97
2354.0
2344.5
-.40
1570.6
1539.3
-1.99
149.8
152.3
1.67
152.9
154.6
1.11
162.7
167.0
2.64
4.4
4.8
9.09
121.8
117.7
-3.37
2555.8
2550.7
-.20
1619.1
1594.9
-1.49
157.8
159.9
1.33
161.3
162.5
.74
169 . 1
173.2
2.42
4.5
4.8
6.67
126.4
123.0
-2.69
2762.7
2775.8
.47
1664.3
1654.7
-.58
166.0
167.7
1.02
169.9
170.6
.41
175.2
179.4
2.40
4.7
4.8
2.13
130.4
129.0
-1.07
3008.9
3030.9
.73
1726.2
1723.4
-.16
174.3
175.8
.86
178.6
179.0
.22
181.5
185.8
2.37
4.6
4.7
2.17
135.9
135.4
-.37
                                                               o
                                                               I

-------
                                                    IAHI.I  II  (cort'd)
Fixed Investment in Nor.rcsidential
Structures,  1975 Dollars
  Baseline projection
  Ivith pollution control costs
  ?o Difference

Housing Starts, Millions of Units
  Baseline projection
  With pollution control costs
  °6 fHffcience
Percentage Growth Rate of GNP,  1975 Dollar
  Baseline projection
  With pollution control costs
  Difference

Percentage Growth Rate of CP1
  Baseline projection
  With pollution control costs
  Difference
Consumption of Other Durables ,  1973 Dollars
  Baseline projection
  With pollution control costs
  % Difference

52.fi
5 2
1 o.l
1 .">
5.13
-1.2
-.6
.6
10.9
11.0
. 1
8.9
8.7
?.25
49.3
49.4
.20
75.1
75.2
.13
51. 1
57. 7
12.02
1 . 40
1 ~(1
-5 ~9
1.8
2.8
1.0
8.7
9.0
.3
6.0
5.0
-16.67
55.0
55.3
.55
75.9
76.9
1.32
52.7
58.8
11 57
1 S8
1 6b
-11 .70
4.7
4.2
-.5
6.8
7.2
.4
6.0
5.6
-6.67
59.4
58.8
-1.03
79.1
80.3
1.52
1976    197"     1978
  55.5    57.5
  58.5    55.9
  5.05   -2.78
  1  05    2.05

-15.03  -15.27
   5.2
   3.9
  -1.3
   6.0
   6.4
 5.5
 4.1
-1.4
 0.0
 6.1
  .1
                                                                                       1979
 58. 3
 53.8
-7.72
 2.00
 1.82
-9.on
  3.7
  3.2
  -.5
  5.8
  5.6
  -.2
         1980
                                 1981
                                19S2
Trade Balance, 1973 Dollars
Baseline projection
With pollution control
% Difference
Consumption of Autos and
Baseline projection
With pollution control
% Difference

costs

Parts, 1973 Dollars

costs

8.9
8.7
-?.25
49.3
49.4
.20
6.0
5.0
-16.67
55.0
55.3
.55
6.0
5.6
-6.67
59.4
58.8
-1.03
7.4
7.3
-1.35
61.8
60.4
-2.27

9.1
8.8
-3.30
62.3
59.7
-4.17

11.1
10.5
-5.41
61.7
59.2
-4.05

J2.5
11.7
-6.40
61.3
59.7
-2.61


13.S
13.0
-5 .
61
61

80
.6
.0
97

•4 7
14.0
-4.7o
62.5
62.0
-.80
  82.4
  83.2
   .97
86.3
86.2
-.12
 89.5
 88.4
-1.23
60.1
55.1
S.32
1.91
1.87
2.ng
3.1
3.6
. 5
5 . 3
5.1
-.4
J2.5
11.7
6.40
61.3
59.7
2.61
91.9
91.0
-.98
63.8
59.6
-6.58
1 82
• 86
1 20
2.8
3 . 7
.9
5 . i
5.0
-.3
13.8
13.0
-5.80
61.6
61.0
-.97
94.4
94.2
-.21
68.1
63.5
-6. "5
l.SS
1 92
2 1 -
j .
-I 2
. 5
5. 1
1.9
•^
•4 7
14.0
-4.?o
62.5
62.0
-.80
97.4
97.6
.21

-------
    TABLE II (cont'd)
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
Consumption of Nondurables, 1973 Dollar^
Baseline projection
With pollution control costs
% Difference
Consumption of Services, 1973 Dollars
Baseline projection
With pollution control costs
% Difference
Disposable Personal Income^ Current Dol
Baseline projection
With pollution control costs
% Difference
Corporate Profits Before Taxes , Current
Baseline projection
With pollution control costs
— • — — % Difference
Corporate Profits After Taxes , Current
Baseline projection
With pollution control costs
— — - %-Difference
Aa Corporate Bond Rate for New Issues
Baseline projection
With pollution control costs
% Difference
353.7
334.4
.21
•
356.5
337.3
.24
lars
985.0
988.8
.39
Dollars
142.2
145.3
2.18
Dollars
86.1
88. 0
2.21

9.58
9.70
1.25
337.3
340.1
.83

340.5
343.8
.97

1089.4
1104.2
1.36

137.1
146.8
7.08

78.6
84.4
7.38

10.59
11.29
6.61
354.2
357.7
.99

352.7'
357.0
1.22

1211.4
1236.0
2.03

158.3
165.3
4.42

90.8
95.0
4.63

10.97
11.85
8.02
370.7
372.7
.54

370.4
373.4
.81

1345.8
1370.3
1.82

181.8
179.1
1.49

103.4
101.8
-1.55

11.47
12.47
8.72
385.7
384.8
-.23

393.2
393.0
-.05

1488.4
1503.8
1.03

209.2
198.0
-5.35

121.0
114.2
-5.62

10.97
11.77
7.29
397.8
394.8
-.75

411.4
407.9
-.85

1629.7
1633.0
.20

227.8
213.8
-6.15

133.0
124.7
-6.24

11.01
11.44
3.91
408.7
405.9
-.69

425.3
421.1
-.99

1772.7
1772.3
-.02

247.7
236.6
-4.48

145.6
139.0
-4.53

11.03
11.23
1.81
419.5
418.4
-.26

437.3
456.0
-.30

1920.8
1925.1
.22

267.1
261.4
-2.13

158.0
154.5
-2.22

10.97
11.16
1.73
Index of Industrial Production, 1973 = 100
Baseline projection
With pollution control costs
% Difference
100.3
101.2
.90
103.6
106.1
2.41
109.7
111.7
1.82
115.2
115.6
.35
120.9
119.4
-1.24
124.6
122.1
-2.01
127.9
126.1
-1.41
131.0
130.5
-.38
432.0
432.1
.02

450.5
452.2
.38

2088.4
2095.0
.32

294.9
290.1
-1.63

175.4
172.5
-1.65

10.87
11.18
2.85

135.6
135.6
.00

-------
                                        -13-
utilization reduces the size of markups in several  industries.   Thus  for  the
1980-82 period the shortfall in real TiNP averages only 0.7%,  and in  1982  the
perturbed real GNP has virtually returned to the baseline level.

Impact on Investment

     Turning to the maior components of investment, we find that constant
dollar purchases of producers durable Roods are up 7.0°o in 1975,  but  most of
this increase represents investment in pollution control  equipment.   Thereafter,
there is a relative reduction in pollution control expenditures,  and the  differ-
ence declines to Q.S* in 1977 and -3.3% in 1979 before returning almost to zero.
Nonresidcntial construction increases 13% in 197S and 5%  in 1977, but reaches a
maximum negative decrement of -8.396 in 1980.  These decrements are due entirely
to higher costs and a lower level of economic activity, since incremental pollu-
tion control investment in total remains positive throughout the decade.

     Housing starts are hard hit and decline by 5.8% in 1975, 11.7% in 1976,
and 15% in both 1977 and 1978.  After that the difference narrows and they are
only 9% below the baseline solution by 1982.  The impact  on housing,  of course,
depends very much on the particular monetary and fiscal policies being pursued
by the Federal government.  The government, for instance, could take steps
directly to aid the housing market.  To determine the impact of such a policy on
prices and GNP growth, we calculated additional simulation exercises in which we
rctumod housing to-its baseline level.  We found that stimulating the housing
industry simply resulted in reducing the amount of funds  available to the remain-
ing borrowing sectors, particularly fixed business investment, and hence had
relatively little short-run effect or. the overall macroeconomic picture.

Impact on Foreign Trade

     The foreign trade balance in 1973 dollars declines slightly in all years of
the simulation period, unlike other components of income and production which
start with positive increments but then become negative around 1978.  The major
cause of this is the increased level of prices over the entire period.  This fac-
tor is offset in part by fluctuations in economic activity.  Hence in 1975, when
both prices and domestic output arc higher, the decrement,  is largest; higher
prices reduce U. S. competitiveness in international markets, while higher output
increases U. S. imports.  In  later years the factors work  in opposite directions.
Prices are still higher, but a lower level of output reduces the demand for imports.
On balance, however, the price effects always outweigh the income effects.

Other Economic Impacts

     The major components of consumption follow the pattern which might be expected.
All sectors show an increase  in 1974 and 1975 and a decrease for -the period 1978-
1981.  Auto sales are relatively harder hit because of the mobile source emission
controls and decline by a peak amount of 4.2% in 1978; this corresponds to about
500,000 cars.4  They also remain below the baseline solution in  1982 when all
other major components of consumption show slight positive increments.  The change
in auto sales is due to .-i combination of factors which include changes in relative
4
 The cost estimates underlying this analysis were based on the April 1973 imple-
mentation schedule announced by the administrator of I:PA in April 1973 and there-
fore do not take account of subsequent modifica.tions of this schedule which will
reduce these costs.

-------
                                         -14-

Sbhometrics
i

 prices, disposable income,  the rate of unemployment,  and credit  conditions.
 Gasoline prices are explicitly included but other operations and maintenance
 costs arc not included in the new car equation.

      Disposable personal income (DPI) in current dollars is slightly above  the
 baseline solution in all years except 1980.  In constant dollars, it follows
 the general pattern of other economic variables; it is higher through 1977,
 lower  for 1978 through 1981, and slightly positive in 1982.  The actual
 changes in constant dollars can be calculated by subtracting the percentage
 changes in the CPI from the percentage changes in DPI.  Corporate profits
 fluctuate much more on both a pretax and after-tax basis.  They rise 7% higher
 in 1975 and 44% higher in 1976 but then decline sharply to a maximum decrement
 of 6%  in 1979.  After 1979, as with other macroeconomic variables, the differ-
 ence between the perturbed and the baseline solution return toward zero, the
 difference being only 1.6% in 1982.  No measure for "constant dollar" corpor-
 ate profits is given, since this term is not easily defined.

      In the financial markets, the Aa corporate bond rate for new issues is
 above  the baseline solution throughout the simulation period.  It is higher
 by 0.7"0  (or a 6.6% increase) in 1975; the difference continues to widen to
 1977,  where the gap is a full 100 basis points (or an 8.7% increase).  After
 that it diminishes somewhat but still remains 0.3% higher (or a 2.9% increase)
 by 1982.  Finally, the index of industrial production ^ollows much the same
 pattern as constant-dollar CNP, with the peak oositive difference of 2.4%
 being  recorded in 1975 and the peak negative di^erence of 2.0°* occurring in
 1979.  The projected levels and differences in interest rates depend, of course,
 upon monetary policy.

 Sensitivity Analyses

      Ko now consider the results of alternative simulation analyses which
 tested changes in the underlying assumptions about the condition of the
 cconom\ or about the level or timing of pollution abatement expenditures.
 First, we summarize the changes that occur when we superimpose the expected
 levels of pollution control costs on the "full employment" baseline.  As
 would  he expected under this scenario, the price increases are slightly
 larger although the differences are modest.  For example, by 1982 we find
 that the wholesale price index has increased by about three-fifths, the
 implicit GNP deflator by about two-fifths, and the CPI by about one-fifth
 more than with the Chase cyclical economic scenario used in the earlier
 analyses.  The declines in real r,NP are also similar  in nature although the
 timing pattern is somewhat different.  The increase in producers durable
 equipment and nonresidcntial construction and the decline in housing starts
 all follow the same pattern.

      The impacts under the "cyclical" and "full employment" cases are similar
 primarily because there is relatively little difference between the two
 economic scenarios.  In particular, the cyclical scenario assumes that the
 unemployment rate averages approximately 4.5% whereas in the full employment
 scenario this rate moves from 44% to 3.9% in 1980 and remains at that level.
 It is  clear that somewhat greater differences would have been observed if
 we had run a true recession scenario with the unemployment rate as high as 6%.
 However, the alternative runs at full employment do indicate that the rise in
 prices, while somewhat greater, is not of major importance, although the
 difference is more significant for the WPI than for the CPI or GNP deflator.

-------
                                        -15-

  hometrics

     For the second sensitivity analysis,  the assumed abatement  costs  were
adjusted by reducing investment costs by 10"« and increasing O&M  costs  by  an
average of 15%.  The purpose of this scenario was to test the impacts  of
increased emphasis upon process change rather than end-of-the-pipe treatment
as an abatement strategy.  This scenario (with the'Chnsc cyclical  economic
base case) shows price rises about one-fourth less than in the original
analysis.  Because prices rise loss, the maximum decrement in real GNP which
occurs in 1979 is les«- than two-thirds as great as in the original analysis.
By 1982 the change in consumer prices is only one-tenth less, but  for  the GNP
deflator it is one-fifth less, and the wholesale price index one-third less.
The housing market declines by only two-thirds as much and the other distur-
bances to the baseline growth pattern are similarly restrained.

     The third sensitivity analysis involved increasing all costs  by 25%  in
order to test the impacts which could be expected in case the EPA/CEQ  estimates
ucre seriously understated.  This analysis showed the wholesale  price  index
rising over one-fourth more by 1982 than the standard case, and  the implicit
f.\P deflator by one-sixth, but the CPT by less than one-twelfth.  These  appear
to be paradoxical results in that the increase in prices is smaller than  the
.idditional increase in expenditures.  However, this is because the economy,
and therefore the Chase nacroccononic model, contain many nonlinear and dynamic
effects.  These nonlincarities are evident in the changes in prices and output
for earlier years.  For example, in 1975 the incremental change  in the wholesale
price index is two-fifths above the standard, and in 1976 the difference  is
about one-third.  These larger than proportional price increases lead  to  a
sharper than proportional decline in real output.  For example,  the decline  in
CNP in 1977 is over twice :is large, and in 1978  it is two-thirds larger.  Thus
the higher than proportional price increases lead, as night uol1 be expected,
to higher than proportional declines in real product ion and increases  in  unem-
ployment; thus increases in wage rates in future yc.irs are lower than  the stan-
dard analysis, hence eventually leading to some mitigating factors affecting
price*..

     In the fourth sensitivity analysis the timing pattern of expenditures  was
evened out ,md in some cases extended beyond 1982 in order to test the impacts
of extending  implementation deadlines.  As expected, phasing in the expendi-
tures more evenly until  1982 does reduce the overall rate of price increase.
In 1982, the  WPI  js one-third  lower, the implicit fiNP deflator is one-fifth
lower than in  the standard run, while the small  increment  in the CPI is not
affected.  The maximum decrement in GNP, which also occurs in 1979, is only
about half as  large, while the increase in the unemployment  rate is only half
as great.  The decline  in housing starts and in  producers durable equipment
purchases and  nonresident i :il construction expenditures  is only about half as
much.  Thus timing patterns are quite important;  stretching out the expenditures
reduces  the effect on output and prices by almost half.

     It could be argued that the very substantial decline in housing is not
indicative of what would actually happen in the economy, since the government
could take steps to aid the housing market.   Thus in our last sensitivity
analysis, we tested this possibility by returning housing to its baseline
level in order to determine whether the effect, in real  growth and  prices
would be substantially different.  However,  we found that this was not. the
case.  Adding funds to the housing market through action by the  Federal
government, and its agencies simply resulted in reducing the amount of  funds
available to the capital goods sector and hence had relatively little  effect
on the overall macroeconomu  picture.

-------
                                        -16-

  hometrics

                                    CONCLUSION

     'Ihe figures supplied by EPA/CEQ on pollution control expenditures for
the period 197.3 to 1982 will nave a noticeable but modest effect on the
overall economy.  During this .ten-year period, prices will average approxi-
mately 0.2°u a year higher than they would have in the absence of these
expenditures', although in the early part of that period (1974-1977) the
CPI increases an average of G.3°s rr.ore, the implicit GNP deflator increases
.in average of 0.4% more, and the WPI increases an average of 0.8T> more per
vear.   The maximum difference of 1,9% -cor prices is reached in 1976.  These
higher prices eventually result in a somewhat lower growth rate of GNP, with
the maximum decrement of 2% reached in 1979, which ivs turn results in a rate
••>f unemployment which is 0.4% higher.  However, the differences gradually
diminish so that by 1982 real growth and employment are at virtually the same
levels which would have occurred in the absence of pollution control invest-
ment,  while prices are only some 2% higher.

     We also experimented with various alternative assumptions concerning
i lie underlying economic scenario and the level and timing of expenditures.
I he increase in prices would be about two-fifths higher if the economy were
operating at full employment throughout this period; however, this, does not
appear TO be a near-term problem.  An increase in expenditures of  25% would
r:« i se the incremental change in prices about two-fifths in the peak years
iind woijld also have a greater negative effect on real growth and employment.
l;iiially, a stretching out of expenditures to level peak year purchases would
reduce the economic effects on output and prices by as much as one-half.

-------