1969
SEWERAGE
 CHARGES
      68
                           70
                                      71
                                                 72
                         U.S. DEPARTMENT OF THE INTERIOR
                 Federal Water Pollution Control Administration

-------
        TOE COST OF CLEAN WATER AND ITS
                 ECONOMIC IMPACT
                   Volune  III

                SEWERAGE CHARGES
        U. S.  Department of the  Interior
Federal Water Pollution Control Administration

                  January 10, 1969
    For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office
                 Washington, D.C. 20102 - Price $1

-------
                         UNITED STATES
               DEPARTMENT OF THE INTERIOR
                    OFFICE OF THE SECRETARY
                        WASHINGTON, D.C.  20240
Dear Mr. Chairman:

This transmits our complete report on sewerage charges, in response to
the Senate Committee on Public Works'  request for  such a study.  That
request was contained in Senate Report No.  1370, dated July 8, 1968.

The sewerage charge study has been included as Volume III, Sewerage
Charges, in a four-volume report to the Congress,  The Cost of Clean
Water and its Economic Impact.  Volume III  addresses itself to methods
of financing wastewater collection and treatment systems and discusses
the considerations pertinent to the selection of a user charge program
by local governmental units as a means for  raising needed revenues.
Based upon a hypothetical model approach, the impact of various user
charge methods on each of several classes of users of wastewater systems
is analyzed.  The findings of this report support  the application of
user charges to finance a portion of the costs of  sewage collection
and treatment systems.  The choice of the most favorable user charge
method should be made on an individual basis by the local governmental
unit concerned due to the myriad factors to be considered in such a
choice.

Volume I, The Report, updates our 1968 analysis of costs contained in
the first report, The Cost of Clean Water,  submitted to the Congress last
year.  The 1969 report recognizes the  progress made in providing waste
treatment for sewered communities while pointing up the need for continu-
ing high levels of investment in upgrading, expanding, and replacing
the capital base which has been provided.   It concludes that the
current and expected short-run rate of investment  in municipal waste
treatment facilities is inadequate to  meet  water quality improvement
requirements by 1973-  Although industrial  expenditure data are sketchy,
they indicate that, in general, industry has a correspondingly more
adequate rate of investment in wastewater treatment facilities.

Volume H, Appendix, provides supporting summary data from the 1962
and 1968 Federal Water Pollution Control Administration Municipal
Waste Treatment Inventories, and the State  water quality standards
implementation plans.  In addition, the Appendix contains State and
industrial comments on the 1968 report.
                            ii

-------
A fourth volume is an industrial waste profile of the organic chemicals
industry which was prepared by several well-qualified firms in the
industrial water pollution control field.  The profile includes (l) a
five year projected range of cost estimates for attaining various levels
of water pollution control by this important industry sector and (2)
improved methodology for projecting treatment cost estimates for other
industries.

We feel that the work reported on here is a significant step forward in
the understanding of the economic aspects of water pollution control.
                                                theInterior-
Hon. Jennings Randolph
Chairman3 Committee on Public Works
United States Senate
Washington, B.C.  20^10

Enclosure
                            ill

-------
                       TABLE OF CONTENTS

                                                              Page

INTRODUCTION                                                     1

    OUTLINE                                                      2

    SOURCES OF INFORMATION                                       3

    DEFINITIONS                                                  4


SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS                                          6

    THE CURRENT POSITION OF USER CHARGES                         6

    DISTRIBUTION OF COST RESPONSIBILITY BETWEEN
      USERS AND NONUSERS                                         8

    THE DISTRIBUTION OF COST RESPONSIBILITY AMONG
      CATEGORIES OF USERS                                       10


THE CURRENT POSITION OF USER CHARGES                            12

    HISTORY OF USER CHARGES                                     12

    TYPES OF USER CHARGES                                       15
        Sewer Service Charges                                   15
        Sewer Connection and Tap Fees                           24

    CHARGES TO OUTSIDE CUSTOMERS                                25

    SEWER ADDITIONS                                             27

    JOINT TREATMENT AND INDUSTRIAL SURCHARGES                   27

    REVENUE FROM USER CHARGES                                   32


DIVISION OF COST RESPONSIBILITY BETWEEN USERS AND NONUSERS      35

    NATURE OF THE SEWAGE SERVICE                                35

    ALLOCATION THEORIES                                         37
        Public Utility Theory                                   38
        Diffused Benefits Theory                                38

-------
              TABLE OF CONTENTS (Continued)
        Historical Theory                                       39
        Added Expenditure Theory                                39
        Alternative Revenue Theory                              40
        Capital and Operating Cost Theory                       40
        Differential Benefits Theory                            40
        Relative Use Theory                                     41
        Joint Committee Theory                                  41

    ROLE OF FEDERAL AND STATE GRANTS                            45


THE DISTRIBUTION OF COST RESPONSIBILITY AMONG CATEGORIES
  OF USERS                                                      46

    GENERAL CRITERIA                                            46
        Equity                                                  46
        Economic Efficiency                                     47
        Administrative Simplicity                               48
        Revenue Adequacy               ,                         48

    CONFLICTS AND FORMULAS                                      49
        Flat Charges                                            49
        Joint Committee Formula                                 50
        Water Use                                               51
        Fixed and Variable                                      51
        Fixtures, Water Meters and Sewer Connections            52

    DISTRIBUTION OF CHARGES AMONG RESIDENTIAL, COMMERCIAL
      AND INDUSTRIAL CUSTOMERS                                  52
        Qualifications of the Model                             58

    INCIDENCE OF USER CHARGES                                   59

APPENDIX                                                        61

    ALABAMA                                                     61
    FLORIDA                                                     63
    GEORGIA                                                     65
    IDAHO                                                       66
    IOWA                                                        66
    KANSAS                                                      68
    MICHIGAN                                                    70
    MINNESOTA                                                   72
    MISSISSIPPI                                                 74

-------
                   TABLE OF CONTENTS Continued)
    NEBRASKA                                                    76
    NEW YORK                                                    77
    NORTH CAROLINA                                              78
    NORTH DAKOTA                                                79
    OHIO                                                        80
    OREGON                                                      81
    SOUTH DAKOTA                                                82
    TENNESSEE                                                   86
    TEXAS                                                       88
    VIRGINIA                                                    92
    WASHINGTON                                                  93
    WISCONSIN                                                   95


REFERENCE CITED                                                 98
                                VI

-------
                         LIST OF TABLES

Table                                                         Page

   1    Percentage Distribution of User Charge Burden
          By Type of Customer and Charge Formula                54

   2    Percentage Distribution of User Charge Burden
          By Type of Customer and Charge Formula                55

   3    1961 Sewerage Charges in Alabama By Number of
          Local Units                                           62

   4    1961 Sewerage Charges at Various Water Volumes
          for Alabama Municipalities                            63

   5    1959 Sewerage Charges in Iowa By Number of
          Local Units                                           67

   6    1968 Sewerage Charges in Kansas By Number of
          Municipalities                                        69

   7    1959 Sewerage Charges in Michigan By Number of
          Local Units                                           70

   8    1965 Sewerage Charges in Minnesota By Number of
          Municipalities                                        73

   9    1965 Sewerage Charges in Mississippi By Number of
          Municipalities                                        75

  10    1964 Sewerage Charges in Nebraska By Number of
          Municipalities                                        76

  11    1963 Sewerage Charges in North Dakota By Number of
          Municipalities                                        80

  12    1962 Sewerage Charges in Ohio By Number of
          Municipalities                                        81

  13    1964 Commercial Sewer Charges in Oregon By Number
          of Municipalities                                     83

  14    1967 Sewerage Charges in South Dakota By Number of
          Municipalities                                        85

  15    1967 Sewerage Charges in Tennessee By Number of
          Local Units                                           87
                               vn

-------
                    LIST OF TABLES (Continued)

Table                                                         Page

  16    1967 Sewerage Charges in Texas By Number of
          Municipalities                                        89

  17    Monthly Sewer Service Charges By Years in
          Texas Municipalities                                  92

  18    1964 Sewerage Charges in Washington By Number of
          Municipalities                                        95

  19    1963 Sewerage Charges in Wisconsin By Number of
          Municipalities                                        97
                              viii

-------
                         INTRODUCTION
     In the post-war period the rate of increase in State
and local expenditures has exceeded both the rate of increase
in Federal expenditures and the percentage increase in Gross
National Product. (1-5)  To partially meet this large increase
in expenditure, State and local governments have raised the
rates of existing levies and introduced new taxes and charges.
In spite of these increased revenue efforts, revenues have not
generally kept pace with expenditures at the State and local
level.   Resulting deficiencies in available funds either have
been covered by larger Federal grants or have resulted in
increased State and local debts.

     Although some studies indicate that this revenue gap may
shrink in the next decade, many municipalities will continue
to experience large deficits unless Federal and State grants
are increased.  The reason for these deficits is twofold.
First,  expenditures are increasing because of greater
urbanization and increased demand for more and better local
public services.  Urban renewal, fire and police, water, sewer,
'and public welfare costs all continue to rise at a fast rate.
Second, at the same time that such expenditures tend to
increase faster than income, it is difficult for municipal
revenues to keep pace with income.  This is partly attributable
to the fact that real property tax is the main source of
revenue.  The base of this tax is shrinking in many
municipalities because of a migration to the suburbs.  As a
result, the yield of the property tax, at constant mill rates,
tends to be less responsive to increases in income than any
of the other major sources of State and local revenue.

     Many municipalities are facing increased resistance from
taxpayers to new taxes and/or increases in existing levies.
In addition, municipalities are unable to use some levies
because the administration of them is too difficult or
because their use is prohibited by the States.   Municipalities
are also running into financial, political, and legal limits
on increases in debt.

     Given these difficulties in raising additional revenue
and the level of the debt, some municipalities have placed
(1) Numbers in parentheses refer to references cited on pages 98-103,
    The description of the fiscal position of municipalities is
    based on references 1 through 5.
                             -  1  -

-------
greater emphasis on service charges.  In addition to being
more acceptable politically than taxes in some municipalities,
service charges are superior to taxes from the viewpoints of
equity and economic efficiency grounds in many cases.

     As indicated  in Volume 1 of this report, municipalities
will face significant expenditures for providing sewage
service.  These large expenditures will likely require
municipalities to  seek additional sources of revenue.  One
possible source of additional revenue is a charge on sewer
users.  Although sewer user charges have been in existence
for several decades, recently there has been increased
interest in them.  President Johnson advocated the use of
them in his 1968 Congressional Message on Conservation and
Water Management.(6)  Professional organizations are also
interested in the  topic.  For example, the American Public
works Association, the American Society of Civil Engineers
and the Water Pollution Control Federation are preparing a
joint report on the financing of wastewater systems.

     The purpose of this volume of The Cost of Clean Water
and its Economic Impact is to examine the role of user
charges in the financing of sewer services.  The analysis
covers many topics but special attention is given to the
following three questions:  (1) What is the current position
of user charges?;  (2) What proportion of capital and operating
costs should be covered by user charges?; (3) How should the
revenue required to pay for the user share of the
costs be distributed among categories of users?  Although
precise answers cannot be given to these latter two questions,
the analysis indicates the solutions which would result from
the implementation of various theories or points of view.
                           OUTLINE

     The first section is devoted to describing the current
position of user charges in municipalities.  First, a brief
history of user charges is given, including an explanation
of why municipalities have adopted these levies.  Second,
the types of user charges are described and some quantitative
information is presented regarding the frequency of use of the
various charge methods.  Third, joint treatment of industrial
and municipal wastes is discussed.  Municipal restrictions and
surcharges on industrial wastes are given particular attention.
Fourth, the revenue obtained from user charges and the
relationship between costs and user charge revenue is described,
                             -  2  -

-------
     In the second section, the division of sewerage costs
between users and nonusers is discussed.  First, the nature
of the sewerage service is analyzed to determine whether a
case can be made for employing user charges.  Next, various
theories and points of view regarding the distribution of
cost between users and nonusers are described.  The allocation
of the nonuser share of costs among categories of nonusers
is then examined.

     The third section takes up the question of allocating
the user share of the costs to the various categories of
users.  General criteria or tests that can be applied
against user charges are described.  These tests are equity,
economic efficiency, administrative simplicity and revenue
adequacy.  Various charge formulas that are currently employed
or which have been suggested are analyzed in terms of these
tests.  Then, using a comparatively large city in the Eastern
U.S., the distribution of revenue burden that would be
assigned to the residential, commercial, and industrial
sectors of the municipality under various charge formulas
is computed.  Finally, the impact of user charges on the
distribution of income is discussed.
                  SOURCES OF INFORMATION


     The description of user charges is based primarily on
studies conducted by the American City Magazine,  the Municipal
Finance Officers Association of the United States and Canada,
the American Public Works Association and 21 State reports.
Most of the State reports are based on surveys conducted by
the League of Municipalities in the respective States.
Unfortunately, these data sources do not give an  up-to-date
picture of user charge practices.  The studies were undertaken
by different groups for different purposes at different times.
Comprehensive studies were conducted by the American Public
Works Association but, unfortunately, the studies are more
than 13 years old.  The other general studies, based on
smaller samples, were conducted over eight years  ago.

     The reports vary widely.  Not only do they differ in
terms of the date of the survey, and the proportion of
municipalities sampled, but also in the questions asked and
the method of presenting the results.  Because reports are
not available for more than half of the States and because
the information is so varied in the reports which were
                             -  3 -

-------
obtained, State comparisions are omitted.  \j  Thus, the
description of user charge practices does not have the
desired degree of precision and, in a few instances, the
material may be out-of-date.

     The Federal Water Pollution Control Administration
is attempting to provide up-to-date data on user charges
by supporting a comprehensive survey of municipalities on
this topic.  More than 2,000 local government units will be
surveyed and the questionnaire is being designed to provide
information on major questions relating to charges.  However
because of the time involved in developing a satisfactory
questionnaire, conducting the survey, and tabulating,
summarizing, and analyzing the survey results, the report
based on the survey will not be available until later.

     Data for the model that illustrates the proportion of
total user revenue that would be paid by various groups of
users under different charge formulas were obtained from
diverse sources.  Water consumption, residential property
assessment values, and number of industrial employees were
obtained from Hittman Associates, Inc. of Columbia, Maryland.
Information on BOD per industrial employee was supplied by the
FWPCA Ohio Basin Region, Cincinnati, Ohio.  Commercial
property assessment values and part of the information regarding
industrial assessment values were obtained from the Department
of Assessment in Baltimore, Maryland.  The number of commercial
establishments was obtained from the 1963 Census of Business,
U.S.  Department of Commerce.  The numb~er anct~pfoperty value
of industrial firms were taken from the U.S. Department of
Commerce, 1965 Census of Manfactures.


                            DEFINITIONS

User Charges - Several definitions of user charges could
have been utilized in this discussion.  One view is that
user charges include all taxes and charges that are utilized
in paying for sewers.  Another view is that user charges
include only the charges that are related to the degree of
use of the sewer system.  The definition adopted here is that
user charges include all levies that are designated as sewer
charges by the municipalities.  Thus where there are no desig-
nated user charges, and sewer costs are financed from special
I/  Summaries of the State reports are given on a State by State
    basis in the appendix.
                             -  4  -

-------
assessments and property tax proceeds, municipalities are
classified as not employing user charges. User charges do
include levies that are not related to the amount of sewer
use, such as a flat monthly charge as long as the municipalities
label them as applying to the sewerage system.

Users and Nonusers - Users normally discharge wastes into the
sewer system.They are often subject to charges designated
as sewerage charges by municipalities.  Nonusers include those
who may obtain some benefits from the sewerage system and who
may pay for part of the sewerage costs, but whose contribution
is not dependent on discharge of effluent into the system.
The most important groups of nonusers are property owners and
the general public which is represented by Federal, State, and
municipal governments.

     Property owners may pay part of the sewerage costs through
the general property tax and special assessments.  When a
special assessment or part of the property tax is earmarked for
sewerage purposes, the line between a user charge and a nonuser
levy becomes blurred.  However, proceeds from special assessments
and the property tax, even through earmarked for the sewerage
system, are generally regarded as nonuser levies.

     The State and Federal Governments may contribute by
providing grants, financed from general tax revenue, to
municipalities for the construction and operation and
maintenance of the sewerage system.  Municipalities may
cover some sewerage costs from general revenue sources.

Sewerage - Sewerage refers to the entire collection,  inter-
ceptor, and treatment system.
                             - 5 -

-------
                    SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
              THE CURRENT POSITION OF USER CHARGES
     The description of user charge practices is based on four national
 studies and 21 State reports.  The following conclusions may be drawn
 from these studies:


1.   There  are  two major  types  of  user charges  - -  sewer
     service charges  and  tap fees.  Sewer service charges are
     monthly or quarterly levies which represent the source
     of more than 90  percent of the  user charge revenue.  Tap
     fees are levied  only when  a customer is first  connected to
     the sewer  system.  Although tap fees account for less
     than 10% of  total user charge revenue they may be
     important  in financing construction of the initial sewerage
     system and of additions for some municipalities.

2.   Approximately 70% of the municipalities over 5,000 in
     population and a substantial  number of municipalities
     below  this size  employ sewer  service charges of some
     type.  Over  three-fourths  of  these  municipalities  have
     adopted such charges  in the last 20 years. There  also
     are several  sewer and utility districts which  levy sewer
     service charges.

3.   There  are  several reasons  for the recent growth in the
     adoption of  user charges,  the most  important of these
     being:  (1)  State and local legal limitations  on the
     amount of  general obligation  debt;  (2)  limitations on
     municipal  tax sources and  on  the taxing power  of
     special districts; and (3) a  rapid  increase in the
     demand for public services at the municipal level.  When
     user charges are combined with  revenue bonds,  State and
     local  debts  are  not  normally  increased.  The financing
     of sewerage  services  through  user charges  therefore
     allows a municipality to employ its taxing power.in
     meeting the  cost of  other public services  such as
     education, roads and  urban renewal.

4.   The formulas used to  determine  sewer  service charges
     are varied but they can be placed into  five general
     categories:  (a) water use, (b)  number  and type  of
                             -  6  -

-------
     plumbing fixtures,  (c)  uniform flat rate (an identical
     charge for each customer),  (d)  modified flat rate(the
     charge varies  by type of  customer),  (e)  size of water
     meter, and size and  number  of  sewer connections.   The
     most  commonly  used formula  is  a uniform or  modified
     flat  rate.   However,  its  use  is concentrated in the
     municipalities below 5,000  in  population.   For municipal-
     ities above 5,000 population,  approximately 65 percent
     base  the charge on water  use.   The  percentage of
     municipalities employing  a  water use charge also  appears
     to be increasing. Many municipalities  that base  the
     levy  on water  use exclude water used for lawn sprinkling
     from  the charge.  The number  of municipalities that base
     the entire charge on the  number and type of plumbing
     fixtures,  size of water meter  and size  and  number of
     sewer connections is estimated  at less  than 10 percent.
     However, some  municipalities  levy a minimum charge based
     on one of  these factors and a variable  charge on  water use.

5.    Over  35 percent of the  municipalities provide sewerage
     service to customers residing  outside the municipal
     boundaries and the percentage  is probably increasing.
     Two-thirds of  the municipalities that service outside
     customers  charge them 50  to 100 percent more than the
     customers  residing inside the municipality.

6.    Nearly all municipalities have  provisions in their
     ordinances that prohibit  the  discharge  of certain wastes
     into  the sewer system.  However, there  are  variations in
     restrictions and enforcement  severity.   Most municipalities
     do not require pretreatment.

7.    Approximately  100 to 200  out  of the largest 3,000
     municipalities levy  a surcharge on  industries that
     discharge  effluents  of  above  average pollutant levels.
     The charge is  commonly  based  on biochemical oxygen
     demand and suspended solids but acid concentration
     and chlorine demand  are also  included in some formulas.
     Many  of the cities which  have  employed  these surcharges
     indicate that  such charges  have had some impact on
     reducing the volume  and the strength of effluents
     discharged by  industries.

8.    The annual per capita yield from sewer  service charges
     ranges from less than $1  to over $60 but the average
     yield is estimated at $7, excluding municipalities
     that  levy a uniform  flat  charge.  The annual per  capita
     yield where a  uniform flat  rate is  used is  about  $5.
                             -  7  -

-------
9.   Statistics relating user charge revenue to sewerage
     costs are sparse,  but it is likely that over two-thirds
     of the municipalities employing user charges more  than
     meet the operation and maintenance costs of the sewerage
     system from this revenue source.  In Texas, for which
     the most extensive data were available, user charge
     revenue exceeds operation and maintenance costs for more
     than 901 of the municipalities employing user charges.
     It is likely,  however, that less than one-third of
     these municipalities obtain enough revenue from user
     charges to meet both operation and maintenance and debt
     service costs.  The ratio of revenue to costs appears
     to be the smallest for municipalities below 5,000  and
     above 500,000  in population.

10.   Sewerage charges as a revenue device must be considered
     within the context of total local government expenditures
     for all purposes.   In spite of increased revenue efforts by
     State and local governments, revenues have not generally
     kept pace with expenditures.  The income shortage  has
     been covered by larger Federal grants and increases in
     State and local debts greater than increases in gross
     national product.   The waste treatment cost covered by
     local governments is usually local cost after deducting
     State and Federal grants; thus the revenue to cost
     picture presented is even less clear in this light.
     The ability to finance all costs in the absence of grants
     is not known.
            DISTRIBUTION OF COST RESPONSIBILITY
                BETWEEN USERS AND NONUSERS

11.  In the second section of Volume III, various formulas for
     dividing sewerage costs between users, (individuals and
     businesses who discharge wastes into the system)  and
     nonusers (property owners and Federal, State and municipal
     governments) are discussed.  It should be noted that an
     individual or business may be assessed costs as a nonuser
     and also as a user if wastes are discharged.  One finding
     is that no matter what opinion one may have about this
     division of costs he can find a theory to support it
     because the formulas vary so widely in terms of where the
     responsibility for the collection and treatment of wastes
     is placed.  However, this report concludes that there
     is a strong case for dividing the costs between users and
     nonusers.  On this basis, a well-designed user charge
                             - 8 -

-------
     system should not cover all of the total construction,
     operation, and maintenance costs of a sewerage system.

          There are several reasons why users should meet a
     substantial share of the costs of the sewerage systems.
     One, users benefit from the collection and treatment of
     their wastes and it is equitable that they pay for this
     service.- A properly designed user charges system will
     enhance the equity charteristics by distributing costs
     in a manner more closely related to service provided than
     will other ways of raising revenue.

          Second, effectively administered user charges can
     also improve the management of industrial wastes.  Charges
     on volume, and sometimes strength of wastes, can create
     an incentive for industrial users to pre-treat, change
     processes and manage wastes more effectively.

          Third, user charges provide a relatively stable
     source of revenue with which to meet sewerage costs
     which allows for a business-like management of the
     sewerage system and provides for an orderly expansion
     and upgrading of the system.

          The case for assigning some of the costs to nonusers
     is less obvious but is no less valid.  First, property
     owners gain from having a sewerage system through an
     appreciation of property values whether or not they
     discharge wastes.  Second, storm water collection in
     combined systems and the availability of sewerage
     service both are likely to have a positive influence on
     property values.  Third, the general public benefits
     from improved water use, disease control, recreational
     opportunities and esthetics.

          The reports suggest that nonusers should bear a
     much greater share of capital costs than operation and
     maintenance costs.  However, no exact division of costs
     between users and nonusers can be specified.  Each
     situation must be examined in terms of the relevant
     characteristics.  For example, property owners should
     bear a smaller proportion of the costs in areas where
     storm and infiltration water is unimportant as compared
     to areas where this water volume is important.  Also,
     policy considerations related to ability to pay and the
     desired rate of investment for controlling pollution
     influence the shares borne by higher levels of govern-
     ment.  Nor can any universal method of collecting the
                             - 9 -

339-679 0-69-2

-------
     revenue be specified; there are several types of user
     charges.  On the nonuser side, property owners may
     meet their responsiblity through a number of means.
     Often, these costs will be met through special assessments
     or through the price of property in cases where de-
     velopers install the sewer system.  Sometimes, nonuser
     costs will be met through general property taxes.

          Some of the formulas described in the report do not
     discuss the role of Federal and State governments in
     the financing of sewer systems.  However, there are
     several reasons why Federal and State grants should be
     used in this area.  These grants will enable the nec-
     essary standard of water quality to be obtained more
     quickly and will encourage municipalities to plan and
     construct sewage systems.  The grants aid municipal-
     ities over the difficult transition period when treatment
     plants are being constructed, the system is under-
     utilized, user charges have not or cannot be depended
     upon to cover the costs, large increases in the property
     tax are politically unacceptable and debt limits are
     nearly reached.  On balance, Federal and State grants
     coupled with regulatory action have tended to stimulate
     investments in waste treatment facilities.
          THE DISTRIBUTION OF COST RESPONSIBILITY
                 AMONG CATEGORIES OF USERS

12.  The third section of the report is devoted to examining
     various charge formulas in terms of generally accepted
     tax or charge canons and in terms of the impact on various
     types of customers and the income distribution.  No
     charge formula is clearly superior to all of the others
     in terms of equity, economic efficiency, ease of
     administration, and revenue adequacy.  For example, a
     uniform or modified flat rate charge is the easiest
     to administer but is deficient in other ways to other
     types of charges.  The so-called Joint Committee
     Formula (a charge based on the volume and strength
     of sewage) appears to be a highly equitable system
     but it is difficult to administer.  A charge based on
     water use scores between the uniform flat rate and the
     Joint Committee formula when all considerations are
     taken into account.

13.  A model was constructed to measure the impact of different
     charge formulas on the various categories of users.  Users
                             - 10 -

-------
     were classified  into  residential,  commercial,  and  industrial
     groups  and the charges  studied  were;  (a)  a  uniform flat
     charge,  (b)  a charge  proportionate to water volume, and
     (c)  a charge proportionate  to biochemical oxygen demand
     discharges.  It  is  recognized that a  uniform flat  rate
     would likely not be used  in an  actual situation as that
     modeled;  however,  it  serves to  delineate  the limits of
     cost distribution.  The amount  paid by each user
     category  if  sewerage  costs  were met by the  property
     tax  was also computed.  Residential users would pay the
     most under a flat  rate  and  the  least  under  a charge
     based on  biochemical  oxygen demand.   Industrial users
     would be  in  the  opposite  position.  Commercial users
     would pay the most  if costs were covered  through a
     property  tax and the  least  if a flat  charge was used.

14.   Under any of the charge formulas,  the proportion of
     income paid  by an individual in user  charges is inversely
     related to the level  of his income.   Charges based on
     water volume and plumbing fixtures are not  as  likely to
     widen income differentials  as a uniform charge.

15.   A municipality,  when  choosing a charge formula, has to
     examine the  alternatives  in the light of  its own
     situation; no general recommendation  that can be made
     at this time would  be of  much value.   In  particular, such
     evaluations  must examine  the trade-off between
     administrative simplicity and equity.   A  water use charge
     appears to be a  good  compromise choice if water is already
     metered;  in  cases  where a variety  of  industrial wastes
     form a large part of  the  sewage brought to  a treatment
     plant,  such as may occur  in a regional system, a charge
     based on  both volume  and  strength  of  waste  may be
     appropriate.
                            -  11  -

-------
            THE CURRENT POSITION OF USER CHARGES
     This section of the report describes the current practices
of municipalities in regard to user charges.

     User charges employed by municipalities can be placed into
two main categories of levies.  One type of levy is called a
sewer service charge or sewer rental and it is generally paid
monthly or quarterly.  The basis for this levy varies among
municipalities.  Commonly used bases include: size of the
water meter; number of plumbing fixtures; quantity of water
purchased; percentage of water bill; and flat rate per period
of time.

     A second category of levies includes charges that are made
at the time the property is connected to the sewer system or
when the property changes hands.  These charges are generally
labelled as connection or tap fees, and inspection fees.  The
charge may be a flat fee but often it is related to the frontage
of the property, the size of the sewer pipe and whether the
street is paved.

                    HISTORY OF USER CHARGES

     A large majority of the municipalities with populations
of 5,000 or more currently levy sewer service charges.
Municipalities with populations below 5,000 also make ex-
tensive use of this source of revenue.

     From an examination of State reports and other literature,
it is estimated that, of the municipalities which responded to
various surveys, 70 percent of those 5,000 in population levy
sewer service charges and nearly all municipalities charge
a tap or connection fee. (19-43)  This estimate of 70 percent is
higher than estimates made by earlier studies reflecting the
growth in the use of sewer service charges in the last decade.
The 1953 study estimated that over 30 percent of the local
Government units above 5,000 in population levied sewer
service charges.(22)  The 1962 study by the Municipal Finance
Officers Association indicated that 63 percent of the local
Government units included in its survey  had sewer service
charges.(19)

     The popularity of user charges is comparatively recent.
Although the City of Quebec, in Canada, first levied a charge
in 1810 and Brockton, Massachusetts and Boulder, Colorado
instituted charges at the turn of the century, very few
                            - 12 -

-------
 municipalities  employed  sewer  service  charges  until the
 depression years.(19)-(20)

     During the 1930-39 period, many municipalities  adopted
 sewer  service charges.  One reason for the institution  of
 charges was the shortage of revenue experienced by  all  levels
 of  Government during the depression.  Several  new charges and
 taxes  were  adopted by State and local Governments during this
 period.  A  second reason for the rapid growth  in charges
 during this period was that many sewers were constructed in  the
 depression  years and user charges were viewed  as a  method of
 paying for  them.  During the war years, there  were  few  charges
 adopted.  After World War II,  the rapid growth of nearly all
 expenditure items at the local level caused municipalities-many
 for the first time-to insitute new charges and taxes.   The
 additional  costs associated with sewage treatment caused part of
 this growth in the use of charges.

     In the 1960-68 period, there was some increase in  the
 number of municipalities employing sewer service charges and
 many municipalities made changes in the sewer  levies.   Most
 of  the changes were increases  in rates, but in some cases the
 structure  and basis of the charge was altered.

     The pattern of sewer charge adoption is demonstrated by the
.survey conducted by the Municipal Finance Officers  Association
 in  1962.(19)  The survey indicates that, of 163 municipalities
 which  gave  the date of adoption, 8 instituted  charges prior
 to  1930, 23 during the 1930-39 period, 33 during the 1940-49
 decade, 93  during the 1950-59  period and 6 during the 1960-69
 period.  The rate of adoption  by decade is shown in Figure 1.
 The reason  for the uneven growth in the number of municipalities
 employing  sewer service charges is that the pressure for
 additional  revenue came during the depression  when  revenues
 declined and in the postwar period when municipal expenditures
 increased  at a rapid rate.

     There  are several reasons for the recent  growth in the
 adoption of sewer service charges.  Many local governments have
 reached or  are approaching the legal limit on  the amount of
 general obligation debt that can be issued.  The combining
 of  sewer service charges with  revenue bonds allows
 municipalities to build sewage facilities without affecting
 the general obligation debt limits.  This method of
 financing sewerage facilities permits municipalities to
 use general obligation bonds in financing other public
 facilities, such as schools, where revenue bonds are not
 generally practicable.  Because of debt limitations
                             -  13  -

-------
100 -

 90 -

 80 -

 70-

 60

 50-

 40-

 30 -

 20

 10 H
          NUMBER OF U.S. MUNICIPALITIES
             ADOPTING  SEWER SERVICE
           CHARGES BY DECADE  1900-1961
            1900-29
1930-39
1940-49
1950-59
1960-S9
            SOURCE: Lennox L. Moak. Sewer Service Charges.
                   Municipal Finance Officers Association of
                   the United States and Canada, Chicago ,1962
                        - 14 -

-------
municipalities have placed increasing emphasis on revenue
bonds in financing facilities other than sewers as well.(17)(18)

     Another reason for the recent attention given sewer
service charges is that municipalities are often restricted
in terms of the tax sources available to them.  Special
districts are also limited in their taxing power.  For
example, income and sales taxes often cannot be levied because
of legal or administrative limitations.  There are also
political limits on the revenue that can tie obtained from
the property tax.  With the rapid growth in the demand for
public services at the municipal level, these limitations on
revenue sources have become more important.  Sewer service
charges have been a relatively popular way of obtaining revenue.
They can be defended on equity ground because they are related
to a service received.  The increase in sewage treatment has made
the relationship between sewerage costs and use of the sewerage
system even more apparent.  Sewer service charges also have
become popular because they often include the entire municipality
and substantial amounts of revenue can be raised with moderate
rates.
                   TYPES OF USER CHARGES

     The nature, basis, and magnitude of user charges vary
greatly among municipalities.  Some municipalities employ
a complex formula for sewer service charges that includes the
type of customer, the number of plumbing fixtures, and the
quantity of water purchased.  Other municipalities levy a
flat monthly charge against all customers.  In some municipal-
ities residential customers are charged on one basis and
commercial customers on another basis.  Similarly, the tap
or connection fees vary among municipalities and are based
on a combination of frontage, number of connections, and
the size of the water meter in some municipalities, and
are simply fixed fees in other local units.

     Municipalities also differ in the treatment of customers
located outside the municipal boundries.   Some local government
units charge both inside and outside customers at the same
rate, while others charge outside customers three times as much
as customers located inside the municipalities.

                   Sewer Service Charges(19-45)

     Although municipal sewer charges are based on many
different factors and, in some cases, a combination of factors,
                            - 15 -

-------
most of the charges can be grouped into five broad categories.
Each category includes several variations of a particular
charge method.  When all municipalities are considered, the
most common levy is a flat charge.  This is by far the most
frequently used charge method for municipalities below
5,000 population.  However, the most frequently used charge
in municipalities above 5,000 population is based on water
use.  This percentage is even higher if only municipalities
above 25,000 population are considered.

1.   Water Use

          The rationale for basing service charges on water
     use is that sewer costs are related to the volume of sewage
     and most of the water purchased by a customer eventually
     ends up in the sewer system.  It is generally regarded
     as the most equitable method of distributing sewer costs
     by experts in the field.  However, it is more complex
     than most other methods.  The popularity of these charges
     varies among States but, in general, formulas based on
     water use are most commonly employed by large cities
     and cities that have large commercial and industrial
     customers.  There is also some evidence to indicate
     that, on balance, municipalities are replacing other
     charge formulas with formulas based on water use.

          There are many different types of charges based on
     water use but the two most commonly used formulas involve
     a percentage  of the water bill and the volume of water.
     In a few cases, a combined sewage and water charge is
     made.  For some municipalities that treat industrial waste
     the charge is based on both the volume of water and the
     characteristics of the sewage.

     a. Percentage of Water Bill. For municipalities
     that charge in relation to water use, the most
     common basis for the levy is a percentage of the
     water bill.  This charge is simpler to compute
     and easier for customers to understand than a
     charge based on water volume.  It also simplifies
     billing because the sewer charge can easily be
     calculated and submitted to customers along with
     the water bill.  The simplicity of this charge method
     is also a cause of some of its problems.  The
     criteria used in designing the water rate schedule
     may not be appropriate to use in setting sewer
     service charges.  For example, the water rates may be
     designed to distribute equitably the operation,
                            - 16 -

-------
maintenance, and capital costs of the water system
among the various categories of users.  This
distribution of costs may not correspond to an
equitable division of sewer costs, however.

     This problem can be alleviated to some extent by
charging a different percentage of the water bill to
various classes of customers.  However, it is difficult
to arrive at tlie correct percentage for a group of
customers and customer reaction is often unfavorable.
Few municipalities employ this variable percentage
method in practice.  Another difficulty with charging
in proportion to the water bill is that the percentage
must be changed when the water rates are changed if
a given amount of sewerage service revenue is desired.
This gives an appearance of a change in sewerage
charges and is difficult to explain to customers.

     The range in the percentage of the water bill
selected by municipalities is from 5 percent to 300
percent.  Most of the municipalities are in the 50
percent to 100 percent interval.  In some municipal-
ities there is a flat sewerage service charge in
addition to the variable charge that is based on the
water bill.  This flat charge is normally less than
$2.00 per month and is designed to obtain a fee from
customers for having the right to use the sewerage
system, independent of the volume or amount
discharged.

b. Volume of Water  .  Municipalities that charge dir-
ectly on the volume of water purchased utilize one of
two  types of rate schedules,  A small number of
municipalities use a flat rate per unit of volume
where volume is measured in gallons or cubic feet.  A
typical charge is $,10 per thousand gallons.  This
method is simple to compute and easy to understand
since it results in a distribution of charges that
is proportional to the volume of water purchased.  This
distribution may not be equitable, however, if
sewerage costs are not proportional to the volume
of water.

     The majority of municipalities that base the
service charge on water volume have a rate schedule
that varies inversely with the volume of water used,
that is, as the quantity of water purchased increases,
the rate decreases.  All of the rate schedules are in
                       - 17 -

-------
terms of blocks of water but the number of blocks
varies.  Some municipalities have only two blocks
while others have more than eight blocks.  The average
number of blocks is approximately five and the rate
(per. thousand gallons) in the first block is generally
a little more than twice the rate in the fifth block.

     In some municipalities the blocks are identical
to the blocks used in computing the water bill and the
rates are roughly proportional to the water rates.  In
these cases, the service charge is similar to a charge
based on a percentage of the water bill.  Most munici-
palities, however, have a rate and block schedule that
is quite different from the schedule used in calcu-
lating the water bill.  This charge method does allow a
municipality to base the charge on one of the deter-
minants of sewer cost,i.e., water volume.  It also
permits the rates and blocks to be related to sewerage
costs rather than water cost.

c. Combined Charges.  A few municipalities make a
combined sewer and water charge.  This has the
advantage of simplifying the billing procedure from
the standpoint of the municipality and presenting
customers with one bill instead of two.  One
disadvantage is that the rate schedule is normally
geared to water costs and incremental sewerage costs
are given little attention.  Another possible dis-
advantage is that customers are not able to make a
distinction between the charges for the two services
and, consequently, cannot relate the charge to the
level or quality of each service.

d. Volume of Water and Characteristics of Sewage.
Several municipalities base the charge on the volume
of water and the characteristics of the sewage.
Charging in relation to the characteristics of the
sewage is an attempt to place the extra costs asso-
ciated with the treatment and disposal of certain
types of sewage on the customer discharging the
sewage.  In most cases, the charge associated with
the strength of sewage is in the form of an extra
charge or surcharge.  It is generally applicable only
to businesses which discharge industrial waste that
is difficult and costly to treat.

     There are some difficulties with each of the
charge methods based on water use but, in most cases,
                       -  18  -

-------
     satisfactory solutions have been found.   One difficulty
     is that some customers may obtain water  that is not
     metered but is discharged into the sewer system.
     Generally, this problem is limited to a  few cus-
     tomers, usually industrial firms, and is normally
     solved by installing sewage meters or by estimating
     the volume of sewage.

          Another problem is the water that is purchased
     by the customer but does not find its way into the
     sewer system.  The most obvious example  of this is
     lawn sprinkling.  Another example is the water that
     becomes embodied in a product during the production
     process.  Allowance is often made for water used in
     sprinkling by basing the sewer charge on the water
     used during the winter.  For example, a  municipality
     may base the sewer service charge on the average of
     of the water bills for January, February, and March.
     Occasionally, the municipalities solve this problem by
     placing a maximum on the service charge.  No
     adjustment is usally made for water that becomes
     embodied in the product; nor do municipalities nor-
     mally charge unpolluted water at a different rate
     even though they place surcharges on sewage that is
     above a certain strength.  The charging  for water that
     does not reach the sewerage system could be elim-
     inated if sewage meters were installed for all cus-
     tomers.  However, this would be a very expensive under-
     taking and the gain in accuracy would probably not be
     worth the cost in most instances.

2.    Plumbing Fixtures

          The number  of  plumbing  fixtures  is  not  a  commonly  used
     basis for levying service  charges  in  most  States.   In a
     few States,  however,  it is used by several cities,  and  in
     Texas it is  the  most  frequently used  charge  method.   In
     some municipalities,  the  charge is based on  the type of
     fixture as well  as  on the  number.   It is quite common,  for
     example,  to  charge  more for  commodes,  garbage  disposals, and
     washing machines  in commercial  establishments  than  for
     other fixtures.   Nearly all  of  the municipalities have  a
     minimum charge  that includes  a  certain number  of fixtures.
     The minimum  charge  is frequently between $.50  and  $3.00
     and includes from one to  four fixtures.

          Municipalities also  differ in that  some charge a
     flat rate per fixture and  others charge  less per
                            -  19  -

-------
 fixture  as  the  number  of  fixtures  increases.   Typical
 charges  are $2.00  plus $.25  for  each  fixture  over
 four;  or $2.00  plus  $.35  for the fifth  through the
 eighth fixture  and $.25 for  each fixture  over eight.
 A few  municipalities base the minimum charge  on the
 number of fixtures and the variable charge on water use.

     There  are  several reasons why a  municipality may
 want to  consider basing the  service charge on the
 number of plumbing fixtures.   In cases  where  the munic-
 ipality  would like to  base the charge on  water use but
 is prevented from  doing so because the  water  works is
 privately owned or water  is  not  metered,  it may be that
 the number  of fixtures is the best indicator  of water use.
 A second reason is that some of  the sewer costs, like the
 diameter of the pipe,  are related  to  the  peak load that can
 be placed in sewers.  The larger the  number of fixtures,
 the larger  the  demands that  can  be put  on the sewer system
 at any one  time.   Consequently,  it could  be argued that
 sewer  costs should be  apportioned  according to the number
 of fixtures. Three, it may  be public policy  to dis-
 tribute  the burden of  sewer  costs  in  a  way that favors low
 income families.   The  number of  fixtures  almost certainly
 increases with  family  income. A charge based on the
 number of fixtures is  likely to  be higher for high
 income families than a charge based on  any of the other
 commonly used formulas.  Fourth, the  mix  of fixtures gives
 a rough  indication of  the characteristics of  the effluent
 discharged  into the  system.   A charge that varies by the
 type of  fixtures can be viewed as  a levy  that is related
 to the strength of the sewage.

     For  each of the  advantages there  are  disadvantages
that are  generally offsetting.  The number of  fixtures
is at best a very crude measure of  water use.   Sewer  costs
are not related to  the peak load of sanitary sewage  in
places  where a combined sewer system exists  because  it  is
constructed to  take storm water as  well  as sanitary
sewage.  Peak loads,  in any event,  are dependent on many
factors,  only one  of  which is the number of  fixtures.   A
sewer service charge  is a rough tool  with which to  re-
distribute income  and it is questionable whether a
municipality should attempt to redistribute  income  through
a charge  based on a service.   The type of  fixture is  also
a very crude indicator of sewage  strength and  it is not
clear that any household sewage should be  subjected to
a special charge.   A charge based on  the number of  fix-
tures is  administratively complex in  that  frequent
                        -  20  -

-------
     inspections  are  needed to  make certain that the charges
     are up-to-date and accurate.   The best case for basing
     the charge on the  number of fixtures appears to be where a
     measure of water use  cannot be obtained.

3.    Flat Rate

          The most popular form of a sewerage  service charge
     among small  municipalities is a flat rate levy where the
     same amount  is charged to  each customer.   A large majority
     of the local government units below 5,000 in population
     employ a uniform flat charge, while large municipalities
     seldom use such  a  levy.

          Service charges  based on a flat rate are paid less
     frequently and are generally less than charges based on
     other formulas.  The  billings are often made on a quartly,
     semi-annual, or  annual basis.  When placed on a monthly
     basis, the rates are  generally in the $.50 to $3.00 range.
     The median charge  is  approximately $1.00.

          Over the past decade, there has been a slight trend
     toward substituting charge systems based  on water volume
     and type of  customer  for a flat rate charge.  One reason
     for this is  that all  sewerage costs have  increased and
     sufficient revenue cannot  be obtained from a flat charge
     on all customers because of the resistance of large
     increases in rates by owners and renters  of single family
     dwellings,  A second  reason for the trend toward more
     sophisticated charge  formulas is that waste treatment
     plants  have become more common.   The  cost  of  these  plants
     is more directly related to the volume and strength of sewage
     than  is the cost associated with  the  collection  system.
     A third reason for this trend is that commercial and
     industrial firms and apartments are becoming  larger and
     increasing numbers of these establishments are being
     serviced by municipal systems.  As a  consequence, the
     inequities resulting from a flat charge  are more apparent.

           The chief advantage of a flat rate  charge method is
     its simplicity.   It does not require  any metering or
     inspections and the billing is simple because the same
     charge  is levied against each customer.  On the negative
     side, the charge is not related to costs,  especially
     treatment plant costs.  Where large quantities of
     effluents are discharged by industrial and commercial firms
     or large apartment houses, and costs  are met  by  service
     charges, families residing in single  family units are
                            - 21 -

-------
subsidizing these large users of the sewerage system.
Thus, since simplicity appears to be its only virtue, the
scope and usefulness of a flat charge is limited to very
small municipalities that do not have any large users.  This
is consistent with the current practice; as pointed out
earlier, this charge formula is found most frequently in
small municipalities.

Modified Flat Rate

     A sophisticated version of the flat rate charge
method is a system where the rate varies by the type
of customer.  Single family homes may be one type,
apartments another, and industries still another.  The
two systems are very similar in that both charges are
a fixed amount per unit of time.  In municipalities
where there are only two or three customer classes, the
difference between the two systems is slight.  In many
of the studies and reports on user charges, the two methods
are placed in one category.

     Although there are many similarities between charges
based on a flat rate and those based on the type of
customer, there also are many differences.  The revenue
yield is generally higher under the scheme that varies the
charge by the type of customer.  Increased revenue is
possible because rates can be increased for certain user
categories while maintaining the standard rates for
residential customers.  The modified system can take into
account the average volume and strength of the sewage
discharged by the customers in each category.  A detailed
customer classification system increases the complexity
of the levy, but a charge based on a customer category
is easier to administer than one based on water volume and
the strength of the sewage.  A system with several
categories can be more easily adjusted to include new types
of commercial and industrial customers with hard to treat
wastes than can a flat charge system because the principle
of charging different rates to various customers is
already established.

     The number of customer categories varies greatly
among municipalities,  In some municipalities there
are only three or four categories and in other local
units there are over 15 categories.  A typical small
municipality would have the following monthly rate
schedule: single residences-$2.00; apartments-$1.50
for the first unit and $1.00 for each additional unit;
                       - 22 -

-------
     cafes  and drugstores-  $4.00; service  stations-  $5.00;
     schools- $40.00; hospitals- $50.00; creamery- $30.00;
     others- $3.00.  Larger municipalities  generally have
     many commercial and  industrial  customers  and, consquently,
     have a more detailed classification scheme.  A  few
     municipalities base  the charge  to  industrial and  commercial
     customers on  the number of employees  as well as the
     type of business.

         Basing the service charge  on  the  type  of customer
     has many advantages.   The charge system is  comparatively
     simple to administer,  the revenue  potential is  high,  and
     it can take into account the average volume and strength
     of the effluent of the customers in each  category.  In
     terms  of charging according to  the volume and strength
     of the sewage, however, this, method does  have some
     shortcomings.  It is crude in that the charge to  the
     different customer categories may  be based  on some rule
     of thumb rather than on an examination of the effluent
     discharged by that category.  The  charge  may also be
     inequitable in that  all customers  in  a given category
     are charged the same amount, even  though  they may vary
     in their use  of the  sewerage system.   A fixed charge
     does not provide any incentive  for a  customer to  reduce
     the amount or improve  the strength characteristics
     of the sewage.  The  modified flat  charge  method appears
     to be  most appropriate where water use statistics
     cannot be obtained or  a water use  method  is judged to be
     too complex.

5.    Water  Meter and Sewer  Connections  A  small  number of
     municipalities base  the service charge on the size of
     the water meter or the number and  size of the sewer
     connections.  The reasoning behind these  charge methods
     is similar to that described for plumbing fixtures.
     The size of the water  meter and the size  and number
     of sewer connections indicate the  actual  and potential
     use of the sewerage  system.t Thus, it  is  argued,
     costs  associated with  the average  and  peak  load
     volumes of sewage can  be best distributed in relation
     to use by charging in  relation  to  water meter or  connect-
     ions.  Although this line of argument  has some  merit, these
     charge methods are crude.  They do not consider the strength
     of the sewage and they are only a  very rough measure  of
     volume.  These charges are, however,  easy to administer.

         Less than five  percent of  the municipalities use only
     charges based on the size of the water meter or sewer
                           - 23 -

-------
     connections and this five percent is concentrated in the
     less than 5,000 population category.  Some municipalities,
     including a few above 5,000, have a minimum charge based
     on the size of the water meter or sewer connections and a
     variable charge based on water use.  A typical schedule
     of monthly rates for a municipality charging on the basis
     of the size of the water meter exclusively would be as
     follows; 5/8" - $1.50; 4" - $50.00; 8" - $100.00; and,
     12" - $800.00.  The rates charged by most municipalities
     are similar for the small meters but there are sizeable
     rate variations for large meters.  Monthly service charges
     based on connections range between $1.50 and $3.00 per
     connection.

                Sewer Connection and Tap Fees

     Nearly all municipalities have connection or tap fees.
These fees are levied at the time the customer is connected
to the sewer system to cover the costs of making the
addition to the system.  However, the large variation in the
charges among municipalities indicates that costs are probably
not covered in some places and that revenues exceed costs in
other municipalities.  Some municipalities levy permit,
inspection, and reinspection fees.  These inspections are made
when the customer is connected to the system, when the property
changes hands, and at certain time intervals (e.g., every
five years).

     As is the case with sewerage service charges, the basis
of the connection fees varies among municipalities.  The
most frequently found levies are flat fees that range from
less than $5 in some municipalities to over $400 in others.
A common charge is $100.  Some municipalities differentiate
between commercial and residential customers in setting the
connection fee.  In most cases, the commercial fee is nearly
double the residential fee.

     Several municipalities have variable charges and the
charge usually depends on one or more of the following factors:
(1) the size of the sewer connection or water meter; (2) the
frontage; (3) the condition of the street; and (4) the location
of the customer.  Under these four conditions, the highest
charges would be levied against a customer who has a large
lot, and lives on a paved street outside the boundries of the
municipality.

     In some municipalities that base the charge on the size
of the sewer connection, the rate varies from less than $5
                            - 24 -

-------
for a four-inch sewer to over $1,.000 for a twelve-inch sewer.
Where the amount of frontage affects the fee, a charge of
between $2.00 and $4.00 per foot is common.  If pavement must
be broken and replaced, the charge often increases as much as
100 percent.  A few municipalities dispense with formulas and
charge a fee that is equal to the cost of the connection.  In
these municipalities and some others, when the formulas are
designed to cover costs, the fee is reduced if some of the
labor and material is supplied by the customer.

     The permit and inspection fees are generally small and
are intended to cover the costs of the inspection and issuing
of the permit.  Nearly all of these charges are less than $10.
                  CHARGES TO OUTSIDE  CUSTOMERS
     There is a large variation among municipalities in the
service provided and the charges made to families and firms
residing outside the corporate limits.  According to the 1953
survey conducted by the American Public Works Association,(22)
65 percent of the cities with over 25,000 population did not
provide service outside the corporate limits.  Of the local
units that provided service outside the municipal boundaries,
over 60 percent charged higher rates to outside customers.

     Since 1953, there has been an increase in the proportion of
local government units that provide sewage service to families
and firms residing outside the municipalities.  In some cases,
this is because a sanitation or utility district has taken
over the sewer function from cities and has expanded the area
of service.  In other cases, cities themselves have expanded
the service area to include customers outside the corporate
limits.

     The state reports indicate that over 50 percent of the
municipalities above 5,000 population provide service to
outside customers.(23-43)  A majority of these levy a higher
service charge against the outside customers.  In some
municipalities the service is provided free to inside
customers but a charge is made to outside customers.  In
others, where a charge is made to both sets of customers,
the basis of the charge is different for each type of customer.
Although this procedure makes it difficult to compare charges,
it appears that the charge is generally higher for outside
customers.
                            - 25 -

   339-679 O - 69 - 3

-------
     The most common method for charging a higher rate for
outside customers is simply to set some multiple of the rate
for inside customers.  The multiple used varies among
municipalities.  The most frequently found practice is to
charge a rate to outside customers that is between 150 and
200 percent of the inside rate.  In some municipalaties, however,
the outside rate is over three times the inside rate.


     Municipalities also tend to charge higher connection
and tap fees to outside customers.  The difference in
connection charges levied against the two different types of
customers varies even more among municipalities than the dif-
ference in service charges.  In some cases, the inside and outside
charges are the same.  In other cases, the inside fee is a token
charge while the outside charge is substantial.  On the average,
the outside connection fees are approximately 80 percent higher
than the inside fees.
     The levying of higher user charges against outside customers
can be justified on several grounds.  Most of these arguments
are based on the assumption that charges should be related to
sewer costs.  One reason for charging a higher rate to outside
customers is that the businesses and residences located outside
the municipality are placed on larger parcels of land.  The
larger lots mean that both the construction and the operation and
maintenance costs may be higher for each outside customer.  A
second reason for the differential in charges is that outside
customers may be located farther from the interceptor sewer and
treatment plant.  This again causes the costs involved in
servicing users located outside the municipality to be higher.
A third reason is that the sewer rates levied against inside
users may not be high enough to cover the operation and main-
tenance cost.  The municipality can obtain additional revenue
from inside customers through special assessments and the
property tax.  This alternative is not open in the case of
outside users, however, so the municipality must levy higher user
charges against them.  Another reason is that the construction
costs may be partially financed through property tax and
special assessment proceeds, and higher user charges are a
method of obtaining a share of the capital costs from outside
customers.  Finally, the sewer system inside the municipality
may have been built at a time when construction costs were
lower than when the outside portions of the system were added.
In addition, some of the inside system may be fully amortized.
In this situation, the outside sewer rates should be higher
than the inside rates.
                             - 26 -

-------
                        SEWER ADDITIONS

     Although many local governments distinguish between
inside and outside customers in their rate schedules, a large
number do not distinguish between old and new customers when
additions are made inside the municipality or sanitation
district.  The increased costs of additions are generally spread
among all customers.   This procedure is administratively simple
but it can be criticized on equity grounds.  The construction
costs associated with the addition are likely to be higher than
the construction costs of the orginal system.  The construction
costs of the old system may also be fully amortized.  Additions
may cause other costs to increase because of greater strain
on the entire system.  If the costs resulting from additions
are spread among all  the users, the old customers are
subsidizing the new customers unless the operation and
maintenance costs of  the old system are much higher than
for the new.  The subsidizing of the new customer by the
old customer also tends to affect the income distribution.
The sewer additions will serve primarily the relatively
high income families  who live in suburbs, whereas the
old system serves, for the most part, the low income
individuals who reside in the core of the city.  Consequently,
income differences will be increased if old customers pay part
of the cost of servicing new customers.


          JOINT TREATMENT AND INDUSTRIAL SURCHARGES

     A growth in joint treatment (municipal and industrial
wastes treated in the same system) has been observed in recent
years and is described in Volume I of this report.

     Primary reasons  for the growth in joint treatment are the
increase in number of sanitary districts and the increase in
the number of industries willing or permitted to join the
waste treatment systems owned by the cities and towns.(18)  The
growth in sanitary districts has been important in the joint
treatment picture because such districts usually take a much
broader view of their responsibilities in pollution control.
By the same token, if the responsibility for water quality
management shifts to  river basin authorities, a further increase
in joint treatment is likely.(57)

     Although a description of the various approaches of
municipalities toward industrial wastes is imprecise because
of lack of data, some generalizations can be made about such
approaches.  In constructing waste ordinances, more and more
                            - 27 -

-------
municipalities are following the format suggested in
"Guide Lines for Drafting a Municipal Ordinance on Indus-
trial-Waste Regulations and Surcharges", a 1959 report of the
American Public Works Association.(7)  Most municipalities have
at least a general provision in their waste ordinances
stipulating that harmful and objectionable materials may not
be discharged into the sewer system.  In some cases there are
several items which are specifically prohibited.  Commonly
prohibited wastes include; certain dairy, meat packing, and
poultry wastes; specific concentrations of oil, grease, paint,
and acids; inflammable items; ashes; liquids above a certain
temperature; and some radioactive materials.  A few munici-
palities will not allow, or allow only with special permission,
the discharge of wastes that have abnormal concentrations of
suspended solids or BOD. However, the allowable concentrations
vary significantly among municipalities.

     For the 24 cities listed in  the 1955 American Public Works
Report on Industrial Waste Disposal,(21) the range of allowable
concentration of BOD and suspended solids is from 250 to 1200
(parts per million) and 200 to  1500  (parts per million)
respectively.  For the 15 cities  that indicated specific limits
on oil and grease, the allowable  concentration is from 100 to
400  (parts per million).  If the  sewage is above these con-
centrations, it must be pretreated before being discharged.
In the 34 cities that gave data on pretreatment, the percentage
of industries within each city  that pretreated wastes ranged
from less than 1 percent to 100 percent.  The median is 20
percent.

     To enforce restrictions on waste discharges, periodic
tests are conducted.  For the 21  cities reporting on this
topic, the frequency of tests ranged from less than one month
to 36 months.(21)  Seventeen of the cities conducted tests at
six-month intervals or less.  The methods of testing also vary.

     Although some cities have very detailed restrictions and
vigorous enforcements, the majority of the municipalities accept
industrial wastes with no examination or pretreatment.  There
are, almost  certainly, some municipalities that are incurring
large costs  by accepting certain  types of industrial wastes.
These costs  are then passed on  to the local taxpayers or other
users.  The  full extent of this problem is not known.

     Another approach that municipalities have  taken toward
industrial wastes is to levy special charges on specific types
of waste.  Although surcharges  might be thought of an an
alternative  to restrictions, in practice many  of the munici-
palities with detailed  lists of restrictions  also  employ
                             -  28  -

-------
surcharges.  There are several industrial charge formulas that
are in existence or that have been advocated by experts.  These
formulas are normally grouped into four categories,(11)

     The constant rate formula is the most commonly used type
of formula and includes some of the charge methods that have
been previously described.  It involves charging on the basis
of a unit such as; water use, number of fixtures, number of
employees, or time period,,  Most sophisticated versions of the
formula include varying the rate by the type of business.  One
example of this latter variation is a charge which is based
on the percentage of the water bill, where the percentage
varies by the type of business.

     Constant rate formulas are simple to administer and they
take into account the differences in the strength of sewage.
They do, however, have some disadvantages.  The rate schedules
are generally constructed on the basis of some crude operating
rules, negotiation with the business in question or,  at best,
industrial averages.   Since testing the effluent of the firms is
not usually involved in setting the rates, the charge is not
directly related to the effluent.  Consequently, it is not
likely to induce a business to improve the quality of its
effluent.  Charges that vary by the type of business are,
however, an improvement over charges that are identical for
all businesses.  For small municipalities where the gain in
accuracy from testing is small in comparison to the expense
involved, this type of charge may be the best choice.

     A Q-Q (Quantity-Quality) formula is usually what is meant
when the term surcharge is used.   Approximately 100 to 200
municipalities use a formula of this type and the number is
increasing,(19-43)  Surcharges based on this formula take into
account both the volume and the characteristics of the sewage.
Generally, the concentrations of suspended solids and BOD are
included in the formula.   Some formulas also include chlorine
demand and other factors.   In most municipalities it is only
the concentrations that are above the "normal" levels which
are subject to the charge.

     The definition of normal concentrations varies among
municipalities.  For the 15 cities presented in the American
Public Works Association Report, (21) the concentrations above
which a charge is levied range from 200 to 1,000 ppm of BOD
and 150 to 1,000 ppm of suspended solids.  The median is 250
for BOD and 300 for suspended solids.  Thus, although the range
is large, most of the municipalities tend to use the average
                            - 29 -

-------
concentration of BOD and suspended solids found in domestic
sewage as the "normal" level.

     A typical Q-Q formula  (14) would have the following form:
C=V(Y! +Y2(B-Bn)+Y3(S-Sn)) where C is the charge, V is the
volume, YI, Y2, YS , are the surcharge rates, B and S are
the actual concentrations of BOD and suspended solids, Bn
and Sn are the normal concentrations of BOD and suspended
solids.  Instead of computing the charge for each, some
municipalities have volume charges that vary by ranges
of BOD and suspended solids concentrations.  The rates
chosen usually reflect an estimate of the cost involved in the
collection and treatment process.  Since the levels of BOD
and suspended solids do not greatly affect the collection
system, the rates for these factors are determined primarily
by treatment costs.

     There are several advantages of employing the Q-Q
formula.   It is an equitable charge in that the characteristics
of the business effluent and the costs associated with those
characteristics are directly taken into account.   Another
advantage of this type of formula is that it provides an
inducement for businesses to reduce the strength and the
volume of their effluent.  The reduction in BOD and/or
suspended solids that followed the introduction of sur-
charges in Cincinnati, Ohio; Otsego, Michigan; Winnepeg,
Manitoba, Canada; some Oregon cities, and other municipalities,
is described in the literature.(9-13)  The officials in these cities
have been very satisfied with the industrial reponse to the
surcharge.  In Otsego, the volume of BOD fell from 28,000 to
22,000 to 15,000 pounds per day in the three billing periods
that followed an introduction of a surcharge.(9)  In Cincinnati,
there was a large reduction in surcharge revenue, which was
based on the amount of BOD and suspended solids in the effluent,
in the first few years that the surcharge was in existance. (13)
This would, of course, indicate that the waste loadings were
substantially reduced as the effects of the surcharge were felt
and industry could make changes to minimize these effects.

     Although the incentive for reducing the amount of BOD
and suspended solids continues as long as the surcharge is in
effect, it appears that most of the reduction is obtained in
the first few years after the surcharge is introduced,  A
surcharge causes industrial firms to immediately improve their
housekeeping procedures and possibly to introduce some waste
pretreatment.  The charge als.o may induce firms to adopt new
processes which produce less waste or that recover the wastes.
After this initial period, however, it appears that the chief
                            - 30 -

-------
effect is to restrain businesses from introducing practices that
would greatly increase the amount of BOD and suspended solids.
In Cincinnati, which introduced a surcharge in 1953, the amount
of the charge has increased for some businesses and decreased
for others over the last decade.  The annual amount of revenue
obtained from surcharges has been usually between $400,000 and
$600,000 during this period.(12), (15)


     The chief disadvantage of the Q-Q formula is that the
administration of the charge is complex.  When the surcharge
is introduced, either the wastes of all firms must be tested,
or an initial charge is made on the basis of other information
and the accuracy of the charge verified by later tests.  In
addition, periodic tests must be performed to make certain that
the charge base continues to be accurate.

     The effluent sampling and testing practices vary by
municipality.  In some cases, samples of the effluent are  taken
at wide intervals of time.  In other cases, samples are taken
several times an hour on a twenty-four hour basis for a week
or more.  The samples are then analyzed or composited and
analyzed to determine the effluent quality.  The cost of the
sampling and testing procedure for a single firm may exceed
$500.  The total administrative cost can be reduced by sampling
only a few firms in each industry, and basing the charges  for
all firms in the industry on these samples.(8)  However, this
method tends to diminish the incentive for an individual firm to
reduce the concentrations of BOD and suspended solids in its
effluent since such a reduction would not lower the effluent
charges.  Inequities among firms would also rise if charges
are not related to costs.

     Another difficulty  in developing a Q-Q formula is in
determining the rates to be applied  to each factor  in the
formula.  Rate development requires  considerable engineering
analysis of the relationship between effluent characteristics
and treatment costs.  In addition, a decision has to be made  on
the levels of concentration that will be defined as "normal".
On balance, the Q-Q formula has much to recommend it.  It
matches charges for the  effluent with the cost of handling it
for each firm and it provides an inducement for firms to reduce
the quantities of undersirable substances discharged into  the
sewer system.  However,  the complexities in sampling and other
administrative factors severely limit the number of munici-
palities that can utilize this surcharge formula.   The complex-
ities also limit the number of businesses that a municipality
will find it worthwhile  to sample  and subject to the surcharge.
                             -  31  -

-------
     The California formula, as it is applied, has two inter-
pretations.  One interpretation is that a municipality should
examine various flat rate and Q-Q charges and select the one
that is most appropriate.  Another interpretation is that
the amount or proportion of municipal taxes paid by the
business should enter the formula.

     The Joint Committee formula (52) requires that all sewer
costs be divided into user and nonuser categories.  A firm's
responsibility for sewer costs would be its share of the nonuser
costs, payable through the property tax or special assessments,
plus its share of user costs, payable through Q-Q type of charge
This formula will be described at greater length in the next
section since it deals with several broad issues.
                 REVENUE FROM USER CHARGES

     The revenue from user charges is only a small proportion
of total municipal revenue.  However, the amount of such
revenue is substantial for some municipalities.  For the 43
largest cities, the revenue from all sewerage sources totalled
$109 million in 1965-66.(16)  This was equal to less than two
percent of total municipal revenue for the 43 largest cities;
however, New York obtained more than $16 million and Detroit
more than $7 million from this source.  In per capita terms,
Cincinnati and Seattle were the leaders with over $10 per
person per year.

     In most cities revenue from sewerage service charges
comprises approximately 901 of total user charge
revenue. (23-43)  The remainder of the revenue is obtained from
connection fees, inspection fees, sale of sludge effluent, and
investment income.

     The yield, on a per capita basis, from service charge
varies greatly among municipalities but a few generalizations
can be made.  The yield does not appear to depend on the type
of formula employed.  Municipalities that charge a uniform rate
to each customer generally obtain less than the average but
the yields from charges based on water use, fixtures, and type
of customer are very similar.

     Excluding the municipalities that levy a uniform rate,
the average per capita yield for all municipalities is approx-
imately $7 per year as estimated from available informa-
tion. (19-43)  This shows an increase from the 1953 Public Works
Study(21) which indicated a per capita yield of approximately
                            - 32 -

-------
$3 per year and the 1962 Municipal Finance Officers Study(19)
which reported a figure of $4.37.  One reason why this current
estimate is higher than those given in previous studies is that
municipalities have increased sewer service rates to take
account of increased costs which have increased both because of
inflation and because of the increase in waste treatment.  A
second reason is that this $7 estimate excluded uniform flat
charges whereas the other estimates included all sewer service
charges.  A third reason is that the proportion of the population
that is serviced is increasing and per capita figures are
generally based on the entire population, rather than the
serviced population.  A fourth reason is that it is likely that
businesses are paying an increasing share of the sewerage
revenues.  The per capita yield is generally below average for
cities over one million population and for municipalities under
10,000 population.

     The variance in the yield increases as smaller munici-
palities are examined.  In municipalities under 10,000 pop-
ulation, many obtain more than $20 per person while many others
receive less than $2.  A very few small municipalities obtain
more than $40 per person.

     In most municipalities, the revenue from user charges
is greater than the operation and maintenance costs of the
entire sewerage system, but is less than the sum of operation,
maintenance, and debt service costs or the sum of operation
maintenance and capital expenditures.  For the bulk of
municipalities there are no data available that indicate whether
the revenue from user charges is greater than the operation,
maintenance, and debt service costs associated with treatment
facilities only.

     For municipalities over 50,000 population, operation
and maintenance expenditures averaged $3.29 per person in
1965-66.(16)  Total sewerage expenditures averaged $9.45 in
the same period.(16)  The per capita revenue from user charges
usually fell somewhere between these values for most munici-
palities.

     In Texas, where current statistics are available, revenue
from sewer service charges in approximately 90 percent of the
municipalities is greater than the operation and maintenance
costs of their sewer systems.(40)  In some municipalities, the
sewer service charge revenue is more than twice the operation
and maintenance costs.  There is some evidence that a few
municipalities derive revenue from user charges that surpasses
the debt service and the operation and maintenance costs.
                             -  33  -

-------
     The 1962 study of City Finance Officers Association
indicates that two-thirds of the cities reporting on the
question stated that sewer services are completely
self-supporting.(19)  This is a much higher percentage than is
suggested in the information given in the previous paragraphs.
There are however, some possible explanations for this dif-
ference.  Many municipalities intend only to meet operation
and maintenance costs from user charges.  This is evidenced
by the fact that in some of the State studies, municipalities
that do not cover debt service and operation and maintenance
costs from sewer service charges still indicate that the
yield from these charges is satisfactory.  Another possible
explanation may be that the respondents to the 1962 survey
excluded storm sewer costs in their calculations thereby
lowering the cost with which user revenue was being compared.

     This examination of user charge revenue and costs shows
that most municipalities are currently obtaining enough revenue
from user charges to completely cover the operation and main-
tenance costs of the entire sewerage system and to make some
contribution toward debt service costs.  The relation between
revenue and cost varies among municipalities, but there is
some pattern to the relationship among population size
categories.  The ratio of revenue to costs is lowest for the
municipalities over 500,000 and under 5,000 population.
                            - 34 -

-------
   DIVISION OF COST RESPONSIBILITY BETWEEN USERS AND NONUSERS

     The division of  the burden involved in providing  funds to
pay for a Government  supplied good or service depends  on many
factors.  Important factors include  the nature of  the  good or
service; and  the interpretation and  relative weight placed on
commonly accepted tax canons such as equity, economic  efficiency,
administrative  simplicity,  and revenue adequacy.   In this
chapter, the  division of cost responsibility between users
and nonusers  and among nonusers is examined.  The  following
chapter takes up the  question of dividing the user share of the
cost burden among categories of users.

                  NATURE OF THE SEWAGE SERVICE

     Governments provide many goods  and services that could
be classified in several ways.  They could be classified by
function, type  and location of beneficiary, Government depart-
ment, or similarity  to goods and services produced and marketed
in the private  sector of the economy.  It is the last class-
ification system, similarity to privately marketed goods and
services that is of  relevance here.   At one extreme, Government
provides goods  and services like national defense  and justice.
These goods and services, which are  often called public goods
or pure public  goods  in the economic literature, (44-55) possess
qualities that  prevent them from being marketed through the
price system because  the benefits are widespread and indi-
visible.  Thus,  it is difficult to determine the amount each
individual or family  is willing to pay for the good or service.
Even if the amount could be determined, there is no way of
excluding an individual or family from enjoying the benefits
from the good or service if he refuses to pay for  it.   For such
goods and services any relationship between costs  and benefits
on the individual level is very tenuous; the costs are usually
covered from general  tax levies.

     At the other extreme, some goods and services supplied by
Government are  similar or even identical with commodities sold
by businesses.   Examples of these commodities include electricity
and the postal  service.  Electricity is supplied by both
private firms and Government.  Likewise, packages  are delivered
by private firms and  some have even advocated turning the postal
service over to a private corporation.  These services can be
easily marketed using the price mechanism because they can be
sold on an individual, basis and the benefits accrue almost
solely to the purchaser.  When these services are provided by the
Government they can be marketed in such a way that they are
self-supporting.
                             -  35  -

-------
     In an intermediate position are goods like education.
Education is divisible and thus, can be sold on an individual
basis, but it yields general social benefits over and above
the financial benefits obtained by the initial recipient.  If
these good or services, called quasi-public or merit wants in
the economic literature,(45),(54) were marketed through the price
system, consumers would only take into account the direct
financial benefits they receive.  Consquently, an insufficient
quantity of such goods and services would be produced.  In these
situations Government often increases the production and con-
sumption of the commodities either by supplying them directly
or by subsidizing consumers and producers of them.  Thus, the
cost of supplying these commodities is met partly through the
charges or taxes on the users or consumers and partly through
general tax levies.

     The position of the service provided by the sewage
collection and treatment system is not clear.  On one extreme
it could be argued that the sewage service is similar to
electricity or the postal service in that the service can be
marketed using the price mechanism.  It could also be argued
that the benefits accrue almost exclusively to those that
discharge wastes into the system because they would have to
find an alternative way of discharging wastes in the absence
of the system.  On the other extreme, it could be argued
the sewerage service is nearly a pure public good.  Sanitary
waste, at least, is a normal consequence of living.  The
disposal of it should be a public responsibility because the
benefits resulting from disease control and the preservation
of recreational facilities are widespread.  In a more moderate
position is the argument that the sewerage service is
similar to a merit want.  Those that discharge wastes into
the system would likely purchase some of the sewage service,
particularly the collection system, becuase it is an efficient
method of disposing of wastes.  However, if the sewerage
service is marketed using the price mechanism, it is likely
that waste dischargers would purchase virtually no sewage
treatment and not as much collection service as compared to
the amounts thought to be socially desirable in terms of
disease control and preserving recreational facilities.  The
nature of the sewerage service is further complicated because
the sewerage system may yield a joint product in that storm
and infiltration water, and sanitary and industrial wastes
are often collected and treated in the same system.

     Given the  lack  of  agreement about  the nature  of  the
sewerage service there  are  several views  that have been
expounded or  could be advocated in regard to  the  division
                            - 36 -

-------
of sewerage costs among groups in the economy.  One division
commonly made is between users and nonusers.   Users generally
include households and businesses that discharge effluent
into the sewerage system.  Nonusers include groups that may have
some obligation to pay for the sewerage system because it aids
in draining property.   The availability of sewerage service
may increase property  values.   The sewerage system may also
provide services that  yield general benefits  such as disease
control.  These services may provide benefits that vary
in scope from a community to the entire country.

     The division of costs into user and nonuser categories may
appear, at first examination,  to be irrelevant since many
individuals and businesses are both users and nonusers.  They
discharge wastes into  a sewer system, own property and pay
Federal, State, and municipal taxes.  However, individuals and
businesses do differ in the amount and value  of property
owned, the amount of State, municipal and Federal taxes paid,
and the volume and type of waste discharged.   Thus, not only
does the form of payment for the sewerage system depend on the
division of cost responsiblity among users and nonusers, but
the amount paid by an individual or business  depends on
this division.

                      ALLOCATION THEORIES

     There are many points of view that could be put forward
regarding the division of sewerage costs between users and
nonusers.  Many of these points of view have been previously
advocated in regard to other Government suoulied goods and
services.(46),(53)  In some cases, the point of view has been put
forward as a single argument rather than as a comprehensive
theory with the assumptions and consequences explicitly stated.
However, an attempt has been made to construct several theories
from commonly held points of view in order to illustrate the
different solutions that could be obtained, and to determine
whether there is any consensus regarding the division  of cost
responsibility between users and nonusers.

     The following theories regarding the division of
sewerage costs stress equity, but economic efficiency  and
administrative simplicity are also considered.  Equity
considerations are more complicated for sewage service
than most other Government supplied goods because there are
differences of opinion regarding the responsibility that
an individual  (business) should assume for the waste he
(it) creates.  There are also differences regarding the
interpretation of benefits received.
                             - 37  -

-------
                     Public Utility Theory

     One view is that sewage service is similar to electric
or postal service and that the sewerage system should be
operated according to the commerical principle.  User charges
should be set at a level where the revenue obtained from
them will cover the entire cost of collecting and treating
sewage.  This theory would encourage the use of revenue bonds so
that the user charges and sewage costs would be directly linked.
The only justification for a government body supplying the
service is that the Government is likely to be more efficient
than a private corporation or that there is some likelihood
that a private firm would act as a monopoly.  This theory
places the responsiblity for sewage with the creators of it.
It also assumes that the costs associated with the collection
and treatment of storm water and infiltration water should be
paid by users.  This public utility concept has been suggested
for many services provided by government.  The argument for
applying this concept to the sewerage system is especially
strong because sewage and water services are often operated
by the same municipal unit.  Water service has been operated on
the commercial principle in many municipalities and it is
argued that this principle should be simply extended to
sewage service.

                    Diffused Benefits Theory

     Supporters of this view conclude that the benefits of
sewage service are diffused throughout the economy.  They
believe that the collection and treatment of storm water
benefits every individual and business in the municipality.
They also believe that the benefits from collection and
treatment of sanitary sewage and industrial wastes extend
to individuals far outside of the municipality as well as those
inside.  This is because individuals in one area are benefited
if another area employs disease control practices and prevents
recreational areas from becoming polluted.  Since the benefits
are so diffused the sewerage costs would be met by the Federal,
State and municipal Governments through general tax levies.

     This theory assumes a "right to pollute" and does not
place any of the responsibility for sewage collection and
treatment on those that create it; consequently, it does not
support the employment of user charge levies.  This theory
may have some merit but it certainly is an oversimplification.
Although it may be difficult to identify the beneficiaries
of the system with a great deal of precision, some individuals
and businesses benefit more than others.
                            - 38 -

-------
                      Historical Theory

     This theory states that the division of cost responsibility
should be the same in the future as it has been in the past.   The
theory does not have any explicit supporters and it has a weak
theoretical basis.  Nonetheless, even when the orginal cost
division has had no logical basis but simply grew like Topsey,
there is often a tendency to perpetuate it.  This is partly
because customers especially businesses,  have made decisions,
such as the location of a plant, on the basis of existing
conditions.  Changes may be viewed as altering the rules in
the middle of the game, thus, this theory may provide the best
political solution.
                    Added Expenditure Theory

     This theory has two variations.  One variation is that
 sewers  exist primarily to handle storm sewage; the second
 variation is that collection and treatment of sanitary and
 business wastes is the prime function of the sewage system.
 This theory has the most relevance, of course, where there
 is  a combined system.  In this situation, which is relatively
 common  in the United States, (50) the user share of the costs is
 likely  to be greater if the second variation of the theory
 is  implemented.


     Under the idea that sewers exist primarily to handle storm
 sewage  it is argued that the cost that would occur if the
 system  handled only storm water should be allocated to nonusers;
 primarily property owners.  Users would then be liable only for
 the additional costs resulting from collection and treatment of
 industrial, commercial and sanitary wastes.  Because these
 additional costs are related to use, they would be financed by
 user charges.  One basis for this variation of the theory is
 that storm sewers existed before sanitary sewers.


      The second variation would argue  that  costs  of  the
 sewerage system, if it  carried only  sanitary  and  business
 wastes, should be allocated  to users and  financed by user
 charges.  The additional cost resulting  from  a combined  system
 would  then be allocated to nonusers.   The rationale  for  this
 variation of the theory is that the  collection and  treatment
 of sanitary and business wastes are  more  important because  of
 disease and pollution  control than  is  the collection  of
 storm water.
                             - 39 -

-------
                     Alternative Revenue Theory

     This theory yields the same conclusion as the public
utility theory; this is, users should pay the entire cost of
the system.  The reasoning behind this theory is that municip-
alities are faced with large expenditure demands for items
that yield benefits which are usually more diffused than
benefits from sewage services.  Since these programs must be
financed through the property tax, it is better to finance
sewage services through user charges because they generally
encounter less resistance than do increases in the property tax.
Consequently, user charges should be high enough to completely
finance the sewerage system.  The theoretical underpinnings
for this formula are weak but it may be a good approach in
terms of public acceptability.

                Capital and Operating Cost Theory

     This theory assigns the responsiblity for the capital
costs of the system to nonusers, primarily property owners,
and the responsibility of the operating and maintenance costs
to users (those who discharge wastes into the system).  The
reasoning behind this theory is that the sewers are generally
connected to each unit of property and, consequently, the
right to use the sewer is related to property.  The amount
discharged into the sewer relates to the degree of use and the
cost of this should be borne by the user.  This formula is
simple but is very crude and arbitrary.

                   Differential Benefits Theory

     Under this theory the cost is divided in proportion to
the benefits obtained from the sewerage service.  Property
owners benefit from the collection of storm and infiltration
water through prevention of damage from floods and leakage
and improved appearance of the property.  Businesses and
individuals, who create the sewage, gain the most from the
collection of sanitary and commercial sewage because they
would have to find other means of disposing of it.  All
individuals, in and out of the city, obtain some benefits from
the collection and treatment of sewage in terms of disease
control and the maintenance of unpolluted streams and lakes
for recreation and other uses.  In a broad sense, the further
an individual lives from the municipality in question,
the less he benefits from the sewage system.  User charges would
only be related to the benefits measured by the cost of alter-
native methods of waste disposal.  Nonusers would pay in
                            - 40 -

-------
relation to the benefits obtained by property owners and
the general public in the form of drainage, disease control,
and greater recreational and other use benefits.

     This theory has a sound base but it does not place any
direct responsibility for pollution control on the creators
of the wastes and it is difficult to implement.  It involves
computing the hypothetical cost, if there were no sewerage
system, of: (1) storm and subsurface water, (2) waste
disposal, and (3) disease.  In addition, the reduction in
recreational benefits and other water uses would have to
be computed.

                      Relative Use Theory

      This  theory requires that  the sewerage system  be divided
 into  parts  such as the collection system and  the  treatment
 plant.   The cost for each part  is then  divided  in proportion
 to  the  relative volumes of sewage flowing  through that part
 of  the  system.  Nonusers, primarily property  owners, pay  for
 the portion allocated to  storm  and infiltration water while
 users pay  for  the share allocated to  sanitary and commercial
 sewage.  This  formula appears simple  but it would be difficult
 to  implement.  The volume of the two  types of sewage flowing
 through different parts of the  sewer  is difficult to determine
 at  any  given time.   It is even more difficult to  determine  the
 average flows  over a period of  time.

                     Joint Committee  Theory

      This  sophisticated theory  was formulated by  a  joint
 committee  of representatives from eight national  organizations:
 American Society of  Civil Engineers,  American Bar Association,
 American Water Works Association, National Association of
 Railroad and Utilities Commissioners, Municipal Finance Officers
 Association, Federation of Sewage Works Associations, American
 Public  Works Association, and Investment Bankers  Association
 of  America.(47)

      The formula divides  the costs between property and users.
 It  involves dividing the  annual  costs into fixed  and operating
 categories.  The fixed costs are further divided  into  the
 collection, interceptor,  pumping station,  and treatment plant
 categories.  The components of  these  subcategories  are  itemized
 in  detail.  These costs are then allocated to user,  storm water,
 future  growth, and  infiltration categories on the basis of  the
 volume  and  characteristics of each type of sewage.   Property  is
 assigned the responsiblity for  the future  growth,  infiltration,
                             -  41  -

   339-679 O - 69 - 4

-------
 and storm water totals.   Roughly the same procedure is  followed
 for operating costs.   They are divided into the collection,
 interceptor,  pumping  station,  and treatment plant  categories
 and allocated to users and property on the basis of volume
 and waste characteristics.  The operating and  fixed costs are
 then totalled for the use and  property categories.   The
 property share is to  be  obtained from special  assessments and
 the property  tax and  the user  share by user charges.

      This  formula has  much to  commend  it.   It  attempts  to
 relate costs  and  benefits  in a detailed and  logical fashion.
 The  cost  allocation is determined by analyzing the  impact of
 the  different  types of sewage  on  the various components of the
 sewerage  system.  In  this  process both the volume and the
 strength  of the different  types  of  sewage  are  considered. (48-49)
 More  recent studies have  expanded this analysis.  One difficulty
 with  the  formula  is that  it is  complex to  implement.

      This  formula has  a  good deal of merit but there are two
 aspects  of it  that are worthy  of more  consideration.  One is
 the  assignment  of the  future growth costs  to property.  If the
 growth is  expected to  result from an expansion in areas where
 sewers are already installed,  but not  used,  the  procudure is
 correct.   If,  however, the increased growth  is  to result through
 an  increase in  the sewage  discharged,  due  to an  increase in
 water consumption, the costs should be allocated to users.  If
 the expansion  is  expected  to result from  further development
 of land,  the  cost should  be shared  between users and nonusers.

     The second aspect of  the  formula  that might be examined is
 the allocation  of the  costs associated with  sanitary and
commercial sewage to  the users.  The case  is strong for
allocating the  collection  costs to  the users because, in
collecting the  sewage, the municipality is performing a function
 that would otherwise have  to be performed by the users
 themselves.  Wastes have  to be disposed of some way and the
municipality can  likely do it at least as well and  at as low
 a cost as the user.

     This is not the case with treatment, however.   Users would.
 not generally treat sewage as a normal course of events.  The
case for charging users for treatment rests on the  argument
 that water is owned by the public and the quality of it should
not be reduced by individuals and firms who use it.  If this
argument is accepted,  it is clear that the cost of  treating
commercial waste should be charged to users.  Otherwise, the
 financial    costs to the business that discharges waste into  the
system would  be lower  than the social costs.  This  would not
                             -  42  -

-------
 conform to accepted definitions of equity and efficiency.
 Under this argument, individuals should also pay for  the cost
 of treating domestic sewage.  If they do not pay for  this
 treatment, they would be shifting costs associated with the
 sewage to future generations if water quality is reduced or
 to other individuals if treatment is performed.

      These1theories yield varied results.  The users share
 varies from 100 percent under  the public utility and alter-
 native revenue  theories to  zero  in  the diffused benefit
 theory.   The share allocated to  the  three levels of gov-
 ernment varies  from zero in many cases to 100 percent under
 the diffused benefit theory.  There  is also a great deal of
 variance  in the share allocated  to property owners.

      Conclusions are difficult to make in light of such
 varied results.  However, many of the formulas assign some
 cost to users and some to nonusers and any consensus or
 compromise formula would allocate some of the costs to each
 group.  in addition to the factors considered in the discussion
 of the theories, strong support can be marshalled on other
 grounds for allocating sdme of the sewerage costs to users
 and some to nonusers,

      There are several reasons why users should meet  a
 substantial share of the costs of sewerage systems.  Users
 benefit from the collection and treatment of their wastes
 and it is equitable that they pay for this service.  If
 municipalities did not operate a sewage system,  users
 would have to find other means of disposing of their  wastes.
 It may be that an alternative way of disposing of wastes
 would be more expensive for users than if they met the full
 costs of the municipal system.  Users charges can also be
 defended on grounds of economic efficiency.   If  businesses
 were not subjected to user charges,  the financial costs of
 production for businesses discharging large amounts of
 waste would be lower than the social costs of production.
 This would result in profits of these businesses being too
 high and/or the prices of the products produced  by these
 businesses being too low.   This, in  turn, would  likely
 distort production and consumption patterns  away from an
 optimal position.2/ A properly designed user charge system
 conforms more to equity and economic efficiency criteria than
 other ways of raising revenue.   This is because_a properly
 designed user charge relates the cost of providing the
 service to the amount or level of service for each customer.
 •^	

—^ This point is covered in more detail in the next chapter.
                             -  43  -

-------
      Effectively administered user charges also can improve
 the management  of industrial wastes.  When industrial
 businesses  are  first  faced  with  charges based on the volume
 or strength of  the effluent they generally change house-
 keeping procedures to reduce the amount of waste discharged.
 Over  a  longer period, they  further reduce the amount of
 waste discharged into the municipal system by changing prod-
 uction  processes or by pretreating the waste.  Some examples  of
 this  are presented in the previous section of this volume under
 the heading "Joint Treatment and Industrial Surcharge".

      User charges also provide a relatively stable source of
 funds for sewerage authorities.   This facilitates planning
 and allows  for  an orderly expansion and upgrading of the
 sewerage system.  In  the  absence of user charges, the funds
 available for the sewerage  system may be subject to
 fluctuations from year to year because of the dependency
 on annual appropriations.   This  disrupts planning and may
 result  in many  short-run  solutions that are cheap at the
 time  but costly in the long-run.

      There  are  also several reasons for assigning some of the
 costs of the sewerage system to  nonusers.  Property owners
 gain  from sewerage systems  because of the collection of
 storm and infiltration water where combined systems exist
 and because property  values are  positively affected by the
 availability of a sewerage  system.

      The general public also benefits from improved water
 use,  disease control, recreational opportunities and esthetics.
 If users were left to their own  devices in waste disposal, it
 may be  that disease control and  recreational opportunities
 would be at a lower level and odors and unsightly views at
 a higher level.

      A  case can be put forward for allocating some of the
 costs to users  and some to  nonusers but no exact division
 of costs between users and  nonusers can be specified.   Each
 situation must  be examined  in terms of the relevant charac-
 teristics.   For  example,  property owners should bear a smaller
 proportion  of the costs in  areas where storm and infiltration
water is unimportant  as compared to areas where this water
volume  is important.   Policy considerations related to ability
 to pay  and  desired rate of  investment for controlling
pollution also  influence  the shares borne by higher levels of
government.  For example, it may be the Federal and State
government  policy to  redistribute income by giving greater
grants  to poor rather than  wealthy municipalities for the
                             -  44  -

-------
construction of sewerage  systems.   It may also be that the
Federal and State  governments  will give larger grants at one
period of time, as opposed to  another, in order to quickly
meet some goal such as  a  standard  of water quality.
     The exact division of costs between users and nonusers
cannot be specified,  but  it can be argued that users should
bear a larger proportion  of operation and maintenance costs
than of capital costs.   This is because many of the operation
and maintenance costs are related  to volume and other
characteristics of the  waste discharged into the system.

     Once the division of the cost responsibility between
users and nonusers is determined,  the question of how the
revenue will be collected still remains.  Again there is
no universal method of collecting  the revenue that can be
specified.  There  are several types of user charge that could
be employed to meet the user share of the costs.  Similarly,
on the nonuser side, there is also a choice of revenue sources.
Property owners may meet their responsibility through a
number of means.  Often,  the property share is met though
special assessments or through the price of property in cases
where developers install the sewer system.  The property share
can also be met through the property tax.

                ROLE OF FEDERAL AND STATE GRANTS

     Some of the formulas described in the previous pages
do not assign any  role in the financing of sewer systems
to State and Federal Governments.   Others assign a small role
at most.  The nonuser share is generally regarded as the
responsibility of  the property owners.  However, there are
several reasons why Federal and State grants should be used in
this area.  These  grants will enable the necessary standard of
water quality to be obtained more  quickly and will encourage
municipalities to  plan and constuct sewage systems instead
of devoting effort to other projects.  The grants aid the
municipalities over the difficult  transition period when
sewage treatment plants are being  constructed, the system
is under utilized, user charges have not or cannot be depended
upon to cover costs, large increases in the property tax are
politically unacceptable and debt  limits are nearly reached.
The use of the Federal and State grants are likely to place more
of the burden on meeting sewer costs on high income receivers
than if the costs  were completely met by user charges because
the Federal and State taxes are more income equalizing, on the
average, than user charges.  On balance, Federal grants coupled
with regulatory actions have tended to stimulate and make
financially possible, investments  in waste treatment facilities.
                            - 45 -

-------
          THE DISTRIBUTION OF COST RESPONSIBILITY
                 AMONG CATEGORIES OF USERS'

     In previous section the problem of allocating sewerage
costs between users and nonusers was discussed.   Once it is
determined how much revenue must be obtained from user charges
in order to cover the sewerage costs allocated to users, the
question of designing a suitable system of charges to collect
this revenue must be considered,  A user charge, like any
Government levy, should be designed to meet the tests of
equity, economic efficiency, administrative simplicity and
revenue adequacy.
                      GENERAL CRITERIA

                           Equity

     Equity is often defined in terms of one of two principles
of taxation: ability to pay and benefits received.  The ability
to pay principle suggests that a levy should be related to the
capacity or ability of an individual to pay the tax or charge.
In practice, capacity or ability to pay a levy is often defined
in terms of income.  This principle, although important in
analyzing the effect of many individual levies and the total
tax system, is not usually given very much consideration in
the examination of user charges.

     User charges are generally justified by employing the
benefits received principle.  This principle suggests that
charges or taxes should be related to the benefits that the
economic unit receives from Government.  In the case of
sewage collection and treatment, the implementation of this
principle means that individuals and firms should be charged
in relation to the benefits received from the sewerage system.

     The benefits of sewage collection and treatment, like the
benefits of many other goods and services provided by the
Government, are difficult to quantify.

     It is usually difficult for an individual to quantify the
benefits received from a service.  The problem is further
complicated because the benefits received are likely to be
different for each individual receiving the same service.  Evefl
if individuals could quantify the benefits received, it is
impossible to make comparisons among individuals in benefit
terms.  If one person states that sewage service is worth
60 benefit units and another states that it is worth 40
                             -  46  -

-------
benefit units, no conclusions can be drawn because the scales
of measurement may be different.

     It is also difficult to measure the benefits received in
money terms.  There is no easy way of observing the amount
that individuals are willing to pay for the service.  If asked,
each individual will likely give a low figure in order to
reduce his charge, and the validity of the answers cannot be
checked.  Another method of determining benefits is to estimate
the cost of the best alternative method of sewage disposal.  As
pointed out in the last chapter, however, it is extremely
difficult to judge what method would be selected as a reasonable
alternative to a sewerage system.

     Because of the difficulties in estimating benefits, the
benefits received principle has often been interpreted as
a cost occasioned method.  Under this method, those using
the service are charged an amount equal to the cost of
providing them with the service.  Thus, if it is judged that
equity can best be served by implementing the benefits
received principle, each individual (business) should be
charged an amount equal to the expenditure that the
Government makes in providing sewage service to him (it).


                    Economic Efficiency

     Taxes and charges levied by governments are often used
as tools to accomplish certain economic goals.  Although
they may be introduced to pursue specific objectives, they
should also be designed to interfere as little as possible with
the generally accepted economic goals of society.  Goals
commonly mentioned include price stablility, full employment,
rapid economic growth, equitable income distribution, viable
balance of payments, and economic efficiency.3/

     The type of user charge employed is not likely to have
any large impact on any of these goals and any undesirable
impact can be easily counteracted by other fiscal weapons
except in the case of economic efficiency.  The charge method
employed by a municipality may affect a business's decision
regarding location, production process, and level of output.
These decisions, in turn, have implications for the efficiency
A/Economic efficiency implies an economic system that maximizes
  the production of goods and services which best satisfy the
  preferences of society.
                             - 47  -

-------
of the economic system.  Usually, economic efficiency can
best be served if the price of each good and service is
equal to the cost of producing and marketing the last unit of
it.  This rule or condition holds for many Government supplied
goods and services as well as those supplied by the private
sector of the economy.  Hence, a user charge for sewage with
given characteristics should normally be set so that it is
equal to the cost of collecting and treating the last unit
of it.

     If the charge is set above  this level several  distortions
occur.  Businesses that require  a large  amount of sewer
service in their production processes are placed at a dis-
advantage with other businesses.   The costs of the  affected
firms will rise and their profits fall unless they can increase
the price or decrease the production cost of their  product.  If
the prices rise, the distortion  is shifted to the consumer
market and individuals who make  large purchases of these
items are penalized.  Similarly,  individuals who are served
by the sewerage system are penalized if  the charges are set
above the cost of collecting and treating the last unit of
sewage.  The reverse situation would occur if the charge is
below the cost of the last unit.

     If the revenues obtained from charges levied on this
basis are insufficient to cover  the user portion of sewer costs
additional levies that do not affect the charge for the last
unit of sewage may be placed on users.  Connection fees are
independent of charges on the last unit  of sewage.   Minimum
charges also fit this criterion in most  cases.


                    Administrative Simplicity

     The user charge should be as simple to administer as
possible.  For the customer, it should be on a base that  is
viewed as fair and easily understood.  From the point of view
of the municipality, a charge should be selected that does
not require overly expensive and time-consuming inspections.
In addition, the charge  should be amenable to a computation
procedure that is inexpensive.


                       Revenue Adequacy

     The chief purpose of charges is  to  obtain  sufficient
revenue to meet the  sewage system costs  allocated  to users.
It is not enough, however, to design  a system of charges  that
                             - 48 -

-------
will cover current costs.  The charge system should be
flexible so that it can easily respond to meet changes in cost
conditions.

     Costs will likely rise in the future through inflation.
Costs will also likely rise because improvements in the
quality of the service, such as a greater degree of sewage
treatment, are likely to occur.

     Costs may also be altered through predictable preference
and technological trends.  For example, it may be that garbage
disposals and commercial water cooled air conditioners are be-
coming more popular, toilets are being designed that use less
water; individuals are taking longer showers; and the price of
chemicials used in treating certain types of wastes is de-
creasing.  The composition of sewerage customers may change so
that there will be fewer single family units and more high-rise
apartments.  There may also be an increase in the number of
industries that will use the municipal system.

     A charge system should be designed so that the revenue will
expand with increases in costs.  It should also be flexible
enough to take into account other changes, some of which are
indicated above, with a minimum of restructuring.
                     CONFLICTS AND FORMULAS

     It is very difficult to design a charge system that meets
all four of these tests  (equity, economic efficiency, admin-
istrative simplicity, revenue adequacy).  A system that scores
well in terms of equity  is administratively complex.  A system
that is easy to administer does not promote maximum economic
efficiency.  These conflicts are clearly indicated in the charge
methods described in previous chapters.  The following discus-
sion tests the various charge methods against the four criteria
just discussed.


                          Flat Charges

     Flat charges per month or quarter that are identical for
all sewer customers are  the easiest of all the charge methods
to administer.  The charge is clear and predictable for the
customer.  For the municipality, the billing procedure is simple.
No calculations are required and the bills can be printed in
advance of the billing period.  The revenue yield is also pre-
dictable.
                             -  49  -

-------
     Flat charges are not adequate, however, when evaluated by
the other standards.  The revenue obtained from these charges
tends to be small because those families living in single units
will not accept a high charge.  They are also unresponsive to
change unless the rate is changed.  Equity, as defined earlier,
is greatly violated by a uniform charge.  There is no relation
between the charge and the cost of treating the sewage of an
individual or business.  An individual living alone pays the
same amount as a hotel or a service station.  The charge does
not support the goal of economic efficiency.  The charge for
additional units of sewage is zero and this is not likely to
be the actual cost.

     Varying the charge by type of customer improves the
formula's rating on the revenue and equity tests without signif*
icantly making the system more complex.  Although it is more
equitable than a uniform charge, it does not take into account
the difference in the volume and characteristics of the sewage
discharged by businesses in the same category.  In addition,
the rate schedule is often constructed so that there is only
a rough relationship between the charge and the cost of col-
lecting and treating the sewage for each category.

     Charging different rates to various categories of customers
does little to improve the score on the economic efficiency
test.  The charge for additional'units of sewage remains at
zero.


                   Joint Committee Formula

     The Joint Committee Formula described in the last chapter
is also used to distribute costs among users.(47)  The fixed and
operating costs allocated to users are apportioned among volume,
suspended solids, and chlorine demand.  (More recent studies
include BOD as well) (52)  Then rates per gallon, per pound
of suspended solids, and per pound of chlorine demand are
computed.  The charge per user is obtained by multiplying
these rates by the three measures of his sewage.  This formula
attempts to equate the charge with the cost of the sewage
collection and treatment for each user.  Consequently, it
conforms to the benefits received criterion of equity.  This
charge is similar to a volume plus surcharge levy.

     The charge is based on the average rather than the
incremental cost of collecting and treating sewage so it does
not score perfectly on the economic efficiency test.  However,
it does rank higher than nearly any other charge system.  This
charge system also is responsive to changes.  It is designed
                             - 50 -

-------
to take account of changes in volume and waste characteristics
as a matter of course.
     The chief weakness of this charge is its complexity.  It
requires a detailed engineering study to ascertain the relation-
ship between cost and waste characteristics.  It also requires
frequent and detailed sampling if the charges are to be accurate.

                           Water  Use

      A charge based on water use scores  between the two previous
methods  on  all  four  criteria  for  sewer charge formulas.   It  does
not  score perfectly  on  any test  but  neither  does  it  score  badly
on  any.

      In  general,  volume is the characteristic of  sewage  that
most influences  costs.   The  collection system is  affected
very little by  most  sewage concentrations,  and  volume  is  the
primary  determinant  of  sewage treatment  costs in  nearly  all
municipalities.   Therefore,  charging on  the  basis of a water
use  formula ranks close behind the  Joint Committee  Formula
on  the  equity and economic efficiency tests. However,  these
water use  formulas  charge on the basis  of  average  rather than
incremental costs and they are not  as accurate  measures  of cost
as  the  Joint Committee  Formula,  even when the rates vary by
type of  business.  Another drawback is  that  they  are not as good
as  the  Joint Committee  Formula in terms  of  adaptability to
change.   This is because they do not make special charges for
wastes  that cause above average  treatment costs.

      In terms of administrative  simplicity,  charges based on
water use formulas are not as good  as uniform charges but
they rank far above the Joint Committee  Formula.   They do
not require a detailed analysis  of  the sewerage system or
wastes.   However, they do require that water consumption be
metered.

                        Fixed  and  Variable

      Under  this method,  the  capital  part  of  the costs  assigned
to users is  obtained  through  tap  fees and minimum charges.
The  operating cost assigned  to users is  recovered through  a
charge on volume.

      This formula adds  the dimension of  tap  fees  to  the  charges
and,  consequently,  is not directly  comparable to  the other
methods.  Although  it  is  not  explicit, the other  charge  formulas
assign a relatively  low importance  to tap fees.   Since capital
                             - 51 -

-------
 costs are often a large proportion of total cost, tap fees and
 minimums would likely be higher under this formula.

      As compared to using water volume alone, this formula would
 score higher on economic efficiency and equity grounds, lower
 in terms of revenue flexibility, and roughly the same on
 administrative grounds.!/

      Higher tap fees and minimum charges would lower the costs
 associated with volume, and  likely bring the cost based on
 volume closer to the incremental cost of collecting and treating
 the  last unit of sewage.  In terms of equity, the formula
 attempts to relate costs and charges for each customer.  As
 for  revenue, placing more emphasis on fixed charges and less
 on variable charges makes it less likely that revenue will
 expand with volume and  time.


           Fixtures, Water Meters and Sewer Connections

      These formulas compare  very closely with each other and with
 flat charges that vary  by the type of customer.  There are, how-
 ever, some differences.  On  the consideration of equity, fixtures
 measure the concentrations in the sewage better than water
 meters and sewer connections but they may be less accurate as  a
 measure of volume.  These formulas are all nearly identical
 when examined on economic efficiency grounds.  The incremental
 cost for sewage is zero in all cases.  As for revenue, fixtures
 are  much more responsive than water meters or connections.
 Fixtures tend to increase with increases in income and popula-
 tion.  In terms of administration, fixtures require freauent
 inspections and changes in billings, whereas charges in water
 meters and sewer connections seldom vary unless there is a
 change in the level of  rates.


   DISTRIBUTION OF CHARGES AMONG RESIDENTIAL, COMMERCIAL AND
                     INDUSTRIAL CUSTOMERS

      In the preceding pages, various charge formulas were
 examined in terms of general criteria or tests.  In addition to
 these general tests which apply to many charges and taxes,
 municipalities may have specific tests or conditions that they
 wish to impose on a charge system.  Municipalities frequently
4/
-This is the case if higher tap fees and minimum charges resulted,
  If these fixed charges are not required, there is no difference
  between the formula and a formula based on water use.
                             - 52 -

-------
wish to avoid placing a large charge on an individual customer
or group of customers.  It may be that the municipality is
reluctant to place a heavy charge on residential customers but
often the reluctance to charge higher prices is directed toward
the business sector.  For example, a municipality may hesitate
to place a high sewerage charge on a particular business or
group of businesses, even though justified by the general tests,
because of a concern that the business(es) may move or expand
its (their) facilities in another location.  This situtation is
likely to be the most common in municipalities that have one or
a few large businesses which employ a large proportion of the
population.(57)  The problem is further accentuated if the
businesses are already faced with decreasing profits or sales and
are also large sewer users.

     To provide more information on user charges, a model has
been constructed to illustrate how the revenue burden from
user charges would be distributed among categories of users
under various charge methods.  Users are divided into four cate-
gories:  residential, commercial, industrial, and other.  The
commercial and industrial categories are further subdivided.
The commerical category is first subdivided into retail, whole-
sale, and service classes.  The retail and service classes are
subclassified to show the charges on businesses that use larger
than average amounts of water in providing their products.  The
industrial category is subdivided according to the Standard
Industrial Classification System.  The residential category
includes apartments as well as other types of dwellings.  The
other category includes hospitals, churches, schools, and insti-
tutions of a similar nature.  In this model it is assumed that
these institutions pay user charges but no property taxes.

     The charge formulas selected are water volume, flat
uniform charge, and one based upon discharge of Biochemical
Oxygen Demand.  In the case of water volume and BOD, it is
assumed that the charges are proportional to these factors.
These relatively simple charge methods are selected partly
because there are statistics available with which to analyze
them.  Other charge methods such as the number of fixtures and
the Joint Committee Formula are not presented because the re-
quired data are not available.


     The distribution that would occur if the revenue is obtained
by the property tax instead of bv user charges is also presented
for the purpose of comparison.  If user charges are not employed^
it is likely that the sewer costs would be financed by property
tax proceeds.
                            - 53 -

-------
      The model  is based on a large Eastern city, which was
 chosen  for several reasons.  One is that it has a diversified
 industrial and  business base.  A second and very important
 reason  is that  detailed data on water consumption are available
 from the work of Linaweaver and Howe(59) and from Hittman Assoc-
 iates,  Inc.(60)  Although many aspects of the model are based  on
 a particular city, it  is not a complete and accurate description
 of any  city, since some of the required data are not available
 in sufficient detail and national averages are used, and because
 of simplifying  assumptions.

      The results of the analysis are presented in the two
 following tables.  In  Table 1, the percentage distributions
 for the major user categories are illustrated.  Table 2 is
 more detailed and shows the percentage distributions by user
 subcategory as  well as by maior category.

                             TABLE 1

            PERCENTAGE  DISTRIBUTION OF USER CHARGE
                   BURDEN BY TYPE OF CUSTOMER
                        AND CHARGE FORMULA
                  Uniform    Water       Volume
                  Flat rate  Sprinkling  (Sprink-
                             Included     ling
B.O.D. Prop.
 load  Assess
Type of Customer
Residential
Commercial
Industrial
Other
TOTAL
94.2
5.3
0.4
0.1
100.0
59.5
9.2
27.4
3.9
100.0
Excluded)
45.7
12.3
36.7
5.2
99.9

32.4
'l5.6
47.2
4.9
100.1

69.8
22.2
8.0
.0
100.0
Source:  Computed using data from:  1963 Census of Business,
         1963 Census of Manufactures; Hittman Associates, Inc.;
         Baltimore Department of Assessment; FWPCA Ohio Basin
         Region, Cincinnati, Ohio

Totals may not add to 100 due to rounding.


      Table  1 shows that the percentage of  the burden on resi-
 dential customers ranges from 94 percent if a uniform flat
                             - 54 -

-------
                                                     TABLE 2

                                  PERCENTAGE  DISTRIBUTION OF USER CHARGE BURDEN
                                     BY  TYPE  OF  CUSTOMER AND CHARGE FORMULA
en
tn
                    TYPE  OF  CUSTOMER
Residential
Commercial
   Retail
     Gasoline Service Stations,
      Carwashers
     Restaurants, Night Clubs,
      etc.
     Other Retail
   Wholesale
   Services
     Hotels, Motels, etc.
     Laundries, Barber Shops, etc.
     Other Services
Industries
   Food and Kindred Products
     Meat Products
     Dairies
     Canned and Frozen Foods
     Grain Mills
     Bakery Products
     Candy
     Beverages
     Mis c . Foods
   Tobacco Mfg.
   Textile Mill Products
   Apparel Industry
   Lumber and Wood Products
   Furniture and Fixtures
                                    UNIFORM         WATER VOLUME
                                   FLAT RATE         SPRINKLING
                                               INCLUDED      EXCLUDED
                        BOD LOAD
                                            0.2
0.6
0.8
1.5
                         PROPERTY
                        ASSESSMENT
94.2
5.3
3.0
59.5
9.2
4.0
45.7
12.3
5.4
32.4
15.6
7.2
69.8
22.2
15.1
0.7
0.7
2.0
.0
1
0.0
0.9
0.8

0
0.0
0.0
0.0
0.0
0.0
0.0
0.0
0.0
0
0
0
0
0


.7
.7



0.4
.0








.0
.0
.1
.0
.0
1
2


0
1
1


2
1
0
0
0
0
0
2





.2
.3
1
3
.5
.'5
.6

7
.1
.5
.5
.1
.0
.7
.1
.3
0
0
0
0
0


.5
.6



27.4
.3








.9
.1
.2
.1
.3
1
3


0
2
2


2
2
0
0
0
0
0
3





.6
.1
2
4
.6
.1
.2

9
.9
.0
.7
.1
.0
.9
.1
.1
1
0
0
0
0


.0
.9



36.7
.8








.2
.1
.2
.2
.4
2.9
2.9
1
6
0.6
3.8
2.0

10
5.9
0.9
2.0
0.2
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.9
0
0
0
0
0


.9
.4



47.2
.4








.0
.0
.0
.0
.0
1
12


0
1
3


0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0





.6
.8
2.3
4.9
.5
.1
.3

1.1
.2
.2
.1
.0
.0
.1
.4
.2
0.3
0.0
0.1
0.0
0.1
                                                                                                    8.0

-------
                                      TABLE 2 (Continued)

                         PERCENTAGE DISTRIBUTION OP USER CHARGE BURDEN
                            BY TYPE OF CUSTOMER AND CHARGE FORMULA
            TYPE OF CUSTOMER
                   UNIFORM         WATER VOLUME
                  FLAT RATE         SPRINKLING
                              INCLUDED      EXCLUDED
                  BOD LOAD
   Paper and Allied Products
   Printing Industry
   Chemicals and Allied Produc.ts
   Petroleum and Coal Products
   Rubber and Plastic Products
   Leather and Leather Products
   Stone, Clay and Glass Products
   Primary Metal Industry
   Fabricated Metal Products
   Machinery, Except Electrical
   Electrical Machinery
   Transportation Equipment
   Instruments and Related Equipment
   Miscellaneous Manufacturing
Other
     Notes:  1.  Source:
0.0
0.1
0.0
0.0
0.0
0.0
0.0
o.o
0.0
0.0
0.0
0.0
0.0
0.0
0.8
0.1
7.9
0.1
0.7
0.0
1.3
2.5
2.2
0.7
0.5
1.4
0.1
0.2
1.1
0.1
10.6
0.1
0.9
0.0
1.7
3.3
3.0
1.0
0.7
1.9
0.1
0.2
1.2
0.0
31.9
0.3
0.2
0.0
0.3
2.0
0.2
0.1
0.1
0.3
0.0
0.0
                        0.1
3.9
5.2
4.9
                   PROPERTY
                  ASSESSMENT
                                                                         ,4
                                                                         ,5
                                  0
                                  0
                                  1.7
                                  0.0
                                  0.2
                                  0.0
                                  0.3
                                  1.2
                                  0.8
                                  0.3
                                  0.2
                                                                       0.6
                                                                       0.0
                                                                       0.0
0.0
             2.
             3.
         1963 Census of Business; 1963 Census of Manufactures; Hittman Associ-
         ates, Inc.; Baltimore Department of Assessment; FWPCA Ohio Basin
         Region, Cincinnati, Ohio.
Values may not add to total due to rounding.
0.0 implies less than 0.05 of one percent.

-------
rate is employed to 32 percent if the charge is based on the
amount of BOD discharged.  The uniform charge places a large
burden on residential customers because there are many more
residential than commercial, industrial, and other customers.
The median rate of 60 percent is obtained if the charge is
based on water volume, with no reduction for sprinkling allowed.
There is a marked difference in the burden borne by residential
customers if an allowance for sprinkling is allowed -- 60 percent
as compared to 46 percent.  Part of this difference may result
from the assumption that the industrial, commercial, and other
customers did no sprinkling.

     In the commercial sector, the percentage ranges from
5 percent if a flat rate is employed to 22 percent if property
assessment is used.  The median is 12 percent which occurs if
a charge based on water volume, with sprinkling water excluded,
is employed.  As shown in Table 2, retail customers would also
pay the most if property assessment is used and the least if the
charge is based on a flat rate.  Customers that are in the
service industries would pay most if a BOD charge is used.

      Industrial  customers bear  the heaviest burden  (47 percent)
when  the  charge  is based  on  BOD and the  lightest burden when
the charge  is  a  uniform  rate (0.4 percent).  The median burden
for industry exists  if the charge is based  on water volume with
no allowance for sprinkling  (27 percent).  A flat rate uniform
charge  on each customer places  a  small burden on industry because
the number  of  industrial  firms  is very small, relative to the
total number of  sewerage  customers.  The burden on  industrial
customers is also  low if  sewerage costs  are financed by the
proceeds  of the  property  tax.   This is partly because  assess-
ments are usually low due to the  difficulty in determining  the
value of  industrial  property.   The charge based on  BOD places
a  large burden on industries because the concentration of BOD
is higher for  industrial wastes than for sanitary wastes.

     Industrial  customers that would pay the most under the BOD
charge are those  that produce chemicals  (32 percent) and food
(10 percent).  These customers  are large water users and also
discharge effluents  that have strong concentrations of BOD.

     The  category  labelled "Other" includes chiefly hospitals,
schools,  and universities.   These customers may not be subject
to any  sewerage  charges by municipalities.  If they are charged
like all  other customers, however, the charge would be the  lowest
under a uniform  rate  and the highest under  a water volume charge,
where there is an  allowance  for sprinkling.  No burden is shown
under the property assessment column because it is  assumed  that
these customers  would not be subject to  the property tax.
                             -  57  -

   339-S79 O - 69 - 5

-------
                   Qualifications of the Model

     The results presented  in the previous pages may indicate a
 degree  of precision  that  is not warranted.  The figures in the
 table reflect  the  general magnitude of the relevant percentages
 but  they are only  estimates.  There are four qualifications that
 should  be explicitly noted.

     First, the data in the tables are partly based on a
 specific city  and  the numbers would be different for most other
 cities.  However,  the relationship among columns would likely be
 similar for most municipalities.  Consequently, attention should
 be focused on  the  relative magnitudes in each row rather than in
 the  precise numbers.

     Second, the data used  in the analysis were not gathered for
 this model but were  collected from many sources.  Some of the
 statistics describe  an Eastern city, some describe an area in the
 midwest, and some  describe  the entire United States.  Collectors
 of the  data include  various branches of the Federal Government,
 a city  government, and a consulting firm.  Combining these
 divergent pieces of  data introduces an unknown amount of error
 into the results.

     Third, and more important, these results do not measure the
 response of customers to various charges.  If a BOD charge was
 implemented it may be that businesses would reduce the amount of
 the  BOD that they  discharge.  If the residential and commercial
 customers did  not  react in a similar manner, the percentage of
 revenue, but not necessarily the total revenue obtained from
 them, would increase.  The city modelled currently charges most
 of its  customers on  the basis of water volume, so these results
 indicate an "after adjustment" distribution of revenue burden.
     Fourth, the charges in the model are not as complex as the
 ones that currently  exist in many municipalities.  Municipalities
 that charge on the basis of water volume generally have minimum
 charges and a  schedule of rates that declines with the volume.
 As compared to a charge of this nature, the charge used in the
 model tends to underestimate the burden on residential customers
 and  overestimate the burden on industrial customers.  The opposite
 is likely true for flat charges.  No municipality as large as
 the  one in the illustration would use a uniform flat rate.  It
 is even unlikely that a city of this size would employ a modified
 flat rate.  If a flat rate that varies by type of customer is
 employed, however, the burden on industry would rise and the
burden on residences would fall as compared to the situation
under a uniform flat rate.  Municipalities that charge in relation
to BOD, have volume  in the charge formula as well.  In addition,
                             - 58 -

-------
only industrial customers are generally subject to the BOD
charge.


                   INCIDENCE OF USER CHARGES

     It was pointed out in the discussion of equity that the
"ability to pay principle" is not an important factor in the examin-
ation of user charges.  The incidence of these charges may, how-
ever, be at least a marginal consideration in choosing between
user charges and other levies and among various user formulas.

     The incidence of a tax or charge refers to the ultimate bur-
den or final payer of the levy.(56)  In some cases, it is not the
individual or business who has the legal responsibility for the
levy who actually bears the burden of the charge or tax.  For ex-
ample, many excise taxes, like the gasoline levy, are paid by
businesses but the ultimate or final burden rests with the consumer
of the taxed product.

     The burden of user charges paid by businesses could be
shared by three groups of individuals.   The burden of the charges
could be shifted forward to the consumers of products sold by
businesses through higher prices.  It could be shifted backwards
in the production process, chiefly to workers, in the form of
lower wage, interest, and rental payments.   The charges many also
remain unshifted.  In this case,  the burden is borne by the
owners of the businesses who obtain reduced profits.  In
measuring the incidence of the charges, the test is not whether
prices, wages, and products change but how much of any change can
be associated with a user charge.

     The distribution of the burden among these groups depends
on many factors.  One important factor is the supply and demand
conditions in  (1) the markets for the products sold by businesses
and  (2) the markets for resources such as labor.  A second factor
is the length of the period analyzed during which price and wage
adjustments could be made.  In general, the longer the period
after a charge has been introduced the more likely it is that
the  charges are shifted.  The charge is also more likely to be
shifted if the charge depends on the level of output, rather
than a fixed amount.

     The allocation of the burden among the three groups -
consumers, business owners, and resource owners  (chiefly workers)
- has a weak but varied impact on the income distribution.  User
charges tend to increase income differences if shifted forward
to consumers, reduce differences if unshifted, and have a mixed
effect if  shifted backwards.
                            - 59 -

-------
     The burden of user charges paid by residential customers is
likely to be unshifted, and consequently, borne by them.   It is
likely that all of the charge formulas discussed in this  report
take a smaller proportion of income as the level of income rises.
Each of these charge methods also tends to increase income
differences more than a property tax which raises the same
amount of revenue.

     In this section of the report, several types of service
charges have been examined.  However, no general recommendation
can be given.  Each charge method has some virtues and some defects.
A municipality, when choosing a charge formula, has to examine
the alternatives in the light of its own situation.  In particular,
such evaluations must examine the trade-off between administrative
simplicity and equity.  A water use charge appears to be  a good
compromise choice if water is already metered.   In cases  where
water is not metered, a modified flat rate may  be best.   In cases
where a variety of industrial wastes form a large part of the
sewage brought" to a treatment plant, such as may occur in a
regional system, a charge based on both volume  and strength of
waste may be appropriate.
                             - 60 -

-------
                            APPENDIX

     This appendix supplements Section One on the current position
of user charges.  The description of existing user charge practices
presented in Section One is based on the existing literature.
This literature includes studies which were conducted in the
1953-1962 period, journal articles, and State reports.

     State comparisons were not presented in Chapter One because
reports were obtained for fewer than half the States and the
material was not reported on any consistent basis.  The reports
differ in terms of proportion of municipalities included, the
type of information presented, and the year in which the statis-
tics were obtained.  Some of the reports include nearly all of
the municipalities in the States, while others only include a
sample of the large cities.  All of the reports indicate the
basis of the user charge, some indicate the variation in charges
that are levied against different categories of users, but very
few reports give any indication of the revenue obtained and the
costs of the sewerage system.

     The following pages summarize the twenty-one available
State reports on a State by State basis.  The scope, topics,
and detail given in the summaries vary from State to State due
to differences in the reports.


                            ALABAMA(23)

     Information on user charges in Alabama is taken from a
report of the Alabama Water Improvement Commission,  The data
were collected during 1960 and 1961.

     The Alabama report includes service charge information on
135 municipalities.  Forty-eight municipalities do not have a
service charge and 25 of the 48 do not provide sewage treatment.
Some of these municipalities that do not have a sewer service
charge have a water charge that is high enough to cover some of
the costs of the sewer system.  Of the 87 municipalities with
sewer service charges, 21 do not provide treatment.  These 21
municipalities charge a flat monthly fee and use the proceeds
of the charge to finance the operation and maintenance costs of
the collection system.

     The most frequently used method  of  charging  for  sewage
 service  is  a flat  fee.  Over  60 percent  of  all  local  units use
 this method, including  all with populations under 2,500.
 Municipalities  with populations over  10,000 tend  to rely on
                            - 61 -

-------
 charge  methods  that  are based  on water use.  Many of the
 municipalities  that  base  the charge  on water volume are served
 by Birmingham and Bessemer, both of  which  charge according to
 water volume.   The following table shows the number of munici-
 palities  using  each  charge method:

                           TABLE 3

                1961  SEWERAGE CHARGES IN ALABAMA
                   BY NUMBER OF LOCAL UNITS

                   	Basis  for Charge	
                                           Percentage of
 Population        Flat Rate  Water Volume      Bill      Total

 Over  100,000                      1                         1
 10,001  -  100,000       25              9         16
  5,001  -  10,000      10           7              4         21
  2,501  -  5,000        16           7              0         23
 Under 2,500          26_           £              £         2£

 TOTAL                54          20             13         87

 Source:   A Summary of Municipal Water and Sewer Rates, State of
          Alabama  Water improvement Commission, 1961.

      The  range  in flat monthly rates  is from $.50 to $2.50 and
 the median is $1.00.   A few of the municipalities that charge a
 flat  rate to  residential  customers levy a charge based on volume
 to commercial customers.

      For  municipalities that base the charge on a percentage of
 the water bill, the  percentage ranges from 25 to 70 percent
 and the median  is 50 percent.  Nearly all of the local units
 that  charge according to  water volume have a schedule that
 declines  as the quantity  of water increases and all of these
 municipalities  have  a minimum  charge.  The minimum ranges from
 $.43  to $3.00 per month and the median rate is about $1.70.  The
 following table has  been  constructed  to show the range of
 charges and the median charge  at various volumes of water.  All
 of the  municipalities included in the table charge on the basis
 of water  volume or the water bill.

     Several of the municipalities levy surcharges  on industrial
waste.  Anniston has  no sewerage charge except for  commercial and
industrial waste that  exceeds  a Biochemical Oxygen  Demand of
210 parts per million.  The charge is related to the strength of
the effluent.   Boaz has a charge to industrial plants that is
                             -  62 -

-------
based on volume and strength.  Decatur, Athens, and Jasper have
an extra charge for firms discharging burdensome sewage.
                            TABLE 4

          1961 SEWERAGE CHARGES AT VARIOUS WATER VOLUMES
                   FOR ALABAMA MUNICIPALITIES
                                Gallons Per Month
High Charge
Median
Low Charge
4,000
$2.04
.90
.52
12,000
$5.50
2.00
1.14
50,000
$16.84
7.40
3.62
200,000
$45.00
23.75
12.89
Source:
         A Summary of Municipal Water and Sewer Rates. State of
         Alabama Water Improvement Commission, 1961.
     Approximately 60 percent of the municipalities charge a flat
sewer tap fee.  This fee ranges from $1.50 to $225.00.  The most
common fee charged is $50.00.  Decatur bases its fee on the size
of the sewer.  The charge ranges from $250.00 for a four inch
sewer to $1,125.00 for a ten inch pipe.

     Some information is also given on the type of bonds that
are issued to finance treatment plants and connection systems.
In financing sewage treatment plants and outfall sewers, 61
municipalities issued revenue bonds and 44 used public improve-
ment bonds and 48 issued other forms of bonds.  In approximately
40 percent of the local units, property is assessed to pay for
the collection system.


                            FLORIDA(24)

     Information on user charges in Florida is taken from a
1967 survey conducted by the Florida League of Municipalities.
The Florida report is based on the survey and it includes infor-
mation on 125 municipalities.

     Over 60 percent of reporting Florida municipalities base
the sewer service charge on a flat rate.  Of these, three-fifths
vary the charge by the number of residential units.  For the
39 percent not charging on a flat rate, approximately 21 percent
                            - 63 -

-------
 charge  on water  volume,  9 percent use  a percentage of the water
 bill,  and most of  the  remaining  9 percent  charge  on  the number of
 plumbing fixtures  attached  to  the system.

     The monthly rate  for a single residence is in the $2-$3 range
 for most municipalities.  The  rate for additional residences is
 generally the same  or  a  little below the rate charge for a single
 dwelling.   In Pompano, for example, the rate is $2.75 for each
 residence.   In Edgewater, the  rate is  $3.50 for a single residence
 and $2.50 for each  additional unit.  Small municipalities that
 employ  a fixed charge  often charge commercial establishments the
 same rate.   Large municipalities tend  to charge a higher flat
 rate for commercial establishments or  else switch to a charge
 based on water use.

     Municipalities that base  the charge on water volume also
 have a  minimum rate.  Most  of  the minimum  charges are in the
 $2-$3  range. The  price  per thousand gallons declines as the
 quantity of water  increases in nearly  every municipality.

     In local units where a percentage of  the water  bill is used
 as the  basis for the user charge, the percentage ranges from
 75 to  110 and the  median is 100  percent.

     Some of the municipalities  that charge in relation to the
 number  of plumbing  fixtures have a minimum monthly charge and
 other  local units  charge at flat rate for each fixture.  For
 example, Wauchula  charges $2.50  for the first six fixtures and
 $.25 for each fixture  between  seven and twelve.  Tallahasse has
 a charge of $.75 for each fixture.  The price per fixture declines
 in many municipalities;  in West  Palm Beach, the price for the
 first four  fixtures is $1.50 and $.25 for each of the next six.
 A few municipalities combine a charge for fixtures with one of
 the other charge methods.  Tallahassee, in addition  to charging
 $.75 per fixture, charges in relation to water volume.

     More than 80 of the 125 municipalities have a connection
 charge.  Most of the connection charges are a flat fee, but 11
 base the charge  on  street surface and lot frontage,  and three
 base the charge  on  sewer pipe size.   The range in flat fees is
 from $2 to  $300  and the median is approximately $75.   In a few
 of the  local units,  both connection and service charges are
 higher  for  outside  customers than for those residing within the
municipality.  The  charge is 100 percent higher for  outside
 customers in one or two cases but the typical increase is
 25 percent.

     Florida municipalities  raise a substantial amount of revenue
from user charges.    Seven cities received more than  $500,000 from
                             -  64  -

-------
this source in 1967.  Tampa received over $3 million, Miami almost
$2 million, Saint Petersburg nearly $1 million, Fort Lauderdale
$875,000, Daytona Beach $658,000, Lakeland $634,000, and
West Palm Beach $590,000.  In per capita terms the range is from
less than $1 to nearly $60.  Most of the municipalities obtained
yields between $8 and $17 and the median yield is approximately
$12.

                            GEORGIA(25)

     The description of user charges in Georgia is taken from a
study by the Georgia Municipal Association in 1965.  The study
is limited to cities with population between 5,000 and 10,000.
Data on sewer service rates are given for 21 cities.

     Five of the cities make no charge for the sewage services
that are provided for residential customers residing inside the
municipalities.  Two of these five cities do make flat monthly
charges to outside customers, however.

     Twelve of the cities levy flat monthly charges to residential
customers residing inside the city boundaries.  The charge
ranges from $.75 to $6.00.  All except one of the cities charge
from $.75 to $1.00.  Two of these cities charge commercial and
industrial customers a percentage of the water bill and a third
municipality bases the commercial charge on the number of sewer
connections.

     Two of the municipalities charge on the basis of the water
bill.  In Monroe, each customer is charged a monthly amount equal
to one-half of the monthly winter water bill.  Elberton charges
residential, commercial, and industrial customers an amount
equal to 40 percent, 25 percent, and 5 percent of the water bill,
respectively.

     One municipality charges in relation to water volume and the
remaining city included in the survey, Rifton, charges residential
customers in relation to the number of taps, and commercial
customers in relation to the number of taps and volume of water.

     The arrangements regarding the acceptance of industrial
waste vary among cities.  Five cities accept industrial wastes
with no extra charge; three accept with payment on a volume or
strength basis; two accept waste with industry paying capital
cost of additions to the treatment facility necessitated by
wastes; two accept wastes with industry paying a surcharge
if the strength is above that of domestic waste; and, three
refuse to accept industrial waste.
                             - 65 -

-------
                          IDAHO(26)

     The information on municipal sewerage charges in Idaho is
taken from a report of the Idaho Municipal League entitled
Idaho Water and Sewer Ratest January 1966. The report includes
over 50 municipalities but information on charges is given
only for approximately 30 local units.

     The most common basis for charges in Idaho municipalities
is a flat monthly amount to all customers.  Approximately
one half of the municipalities charge on this basis.  Another
quarter of the local units use a monthly charge, but vary
the charge according to the number of residences in a building
and the type of commercial establishment served by the system.
Most of the remaining municipalities charge according to the
quantity of water purchased, but a few use a percentage of
the water bill and other forms of charges.  A few of the local
units use a combination of charges.  Residences and small
commercial establishments are charged a flat amount and large
businesses are charged in relation to quantities of water
used.  The municipalities which employ charges based on water
use also generally have a minimum charge.  As is true in most
States, it is the smaller municipalities which use the flat
monthly charge method.

     For municipalities levying a flat charge per month or
quarter, the average charge is approximately $1.75 per month.
The largest number of municipalities charge $1.50 but a> few
charge substantially more than this.  Some of the local units
that vary the monthly charge by the type of establishment
have only two or three categories and others such as Kamiah
have a very detailed list  of categories.  The charge for
most commercial establishments is less than twice the charge
for single family homes.  For municipalities that charge in
relation to water use, the rate declines as the amount of
water used increases.  For example, Boise has a minimum charge
of $.80 and charges $.13 for the first 1000 cu. ft.  The rate
then declines to $.09 for amounts  over 5,000 cu. ft.
                              IOWA(27)

     The information on Iowa is taken from a 1959 report of
the Iowa State Department of Health on municipal sewer rental
ordinances.  This material is supplemented by 1968 statistics
for 19 municipalities.  Some municipalities have no doubt
changed the form and amount of their sewerage rates since
1959.  However, using other States as a guide, it seems safe
                             -  66  -

-------
to conclude that at least three-fourths of the local units
are currently employing the same charge as they did in 1959.

     Charge methods based on water use are very prevalent
in Iowa. All of the municipalities with population over 2,500
and approximately 85 percent of all local units base the sewerage
charge on water use.  The remaining 15 percent of the municipalities
levy a flat fee.  Nearly two-thirds of the local units employing
a water use measure base the charge on the water bill and
the other one-third charge according to the volume of water.
The  following table illustrates the distribution of charge
methods by size of municipality.

                            TABLE 5

                 1959 SEWERAGE CHARGES IN IOWA
                    BY NUMBER OF LOCAL UNITS

                	   Charge Basis	
                            Volume ofPercentage of
Population      Flat Rate   Water Used      Water Bill   Total

Over 100,000                    1
10,001-100,000                  8                8
5,001-10,000                    5                7
2,501-5,000                     8               13
1,000-2,500         10          11               24
Under 1,000         \2_          _6               2±

TOTAL               22          39               73       134

Source:  Sewer Rental Ordinances in Iowa Cities and Towns, Iowa
         State Department of Health, Division of Public Health
         Engineering, January 1959.

     For the municipalities basing the charge on a percentage
of  the water bill, the range in percentages is from 10 to
100 percent.  Over  two-thirds of the local units use a percentage
between 25 and 50 percent and the median is 40 percent.  Many
of the municipalities also levy a minimum charge that is roughly
$.50 per month.

     The local units which base the charge on the volume of
water generally have a rate schedule that declines as the
quantity of water increases.  There is, however, a higher
percentage of municipalities in Iowa that charge a flat rate
per gallon than in  most States.  The rate per gallon commonly
ranges between $.05 and $.10 per thousand gallons.  Nearly
                             -  67  -

-------
all of the local units that base the levy on water volume
have an additional flat fee or minimum charge.  The flat fee
generally ranges between $.50 and $1.00 per month.


     The municipalities that charge a flat fee for residences
often have a schedule of rates for commercial customers.  For
example, Lake Mills charges residences $1, schools $50, a
creamery $30, and banks $2 per month.


     Surcharges for industrial effluents are much more prevalent
in Iowa than in most other States.  More than ten municipalities
have explicit charges for industrial effluent above a certain
strength and another 20 to 30 local units have provisions
for making extra charges for industrial wastes.  These charges
take many forms.  In Charles City and Hampton the Biochemical
Oxygen Demand (BOD) above 400 parts per million is multiplied
by the volume of sewage and a rate of $.002 per gallon.  Boone
ranks industries on a BOD scale and charges an industry a
higher percentage of the water bill the higher it is on the
scale. Des Moines takes into account both BOD and suspended
solids in  its charge scheme.  Iowa City, which bases its
sewerage charge on the volume of water, varies the rate according
to the BOD of the industrial effluent.  Coon Rapids gives
a credit for unpolluted water.
                            KANSAS(28)


     The material  on  Kansas  is  taken from  the 1968 League of
Kansas Municipalities report titled:  Sewage Service Charges
in Kansas Cities.


     Many of the current  sewerage charges  levied by Kansas
municipalities  are derived  from,recently enacted ordinances.
Nearly all of the municipal  ordinances pertaining to sewerage
charges were enacted  since  1955 and the majority of the
ordinances were enacted after 1960.


     A flat monthly rate  is  the most frequently used sewerage
charge in Kansas.  Second in frequency of  use is volume of
water, and the  percentage of water bill charge ranks third.
As is true in most States,  nearly all of the small municipalities
                            - 68 -

-------
employ a flat rate charge.  The following table indicates
the use of the various charge methods by Kansas municipalities:
Population

Over 50,000
25,001-50,000
10,001-25,000
5,001-10,000
2,501-5,000
1,000-2,500
Under 1,000
TOTAL
Source:
                            TABLE 6

                1968 SEWERAGE CHARGES IN KANSAS
                  BY NUMBER OF MUNICIPALITIES

                	Basis for Charge
       Flat Rate
           6
           3
          24
          43
          87_

         164
Volume of
Water Used

    2
    2
    9
    5
    8
    6
   37
Percentage or
 Water Bill
      2
      5
      3
     14
Total

  3
  2
 15
 10
 37
 52
 96

215
League of Kansas Municipalities, Sewerage Service Charges
in Kansas Cities, June 1968.
     The rates vary  among municipalities  that employ  the same
method of charging for  sewage  services.   The flat  rates vary from
$.25 to $5 per month.   The median monthly charge is approximately
$1.  Nearly all of the  municipalities which base the  user
charge on volume of  water have minimum charges.  The  median
average charge is $1 per month but  the amount ranges  from
$.70 to $2.50. Some  of  the municipalities charge for  water
at  a fixed rate per  gallon or  cubic foot  and others charge
at  a declining rate  as  more water is used.  A common  fixed
rate is $.10 per thousand gallons.   For municipalities that
base the charge on a percentage of  the water bill, the median
percentage is 50 percent and the range is from  20  percent
to  100 percent,

     The above statistics are  for a single family  within the
city. Many of the municipalities that use a flat rate also
increase the charge  for multiple family units.  The increased
charge usually takes the form  of increasing the rate, often
100 percent.  A few  municipalities  that levy a  flat charge
on  single family  dwellings also levy a charge  on  water use
for multiple dwellings.
                             -  69  -

-------
     Nearly half of the municipalities charge customers outside
the city more than those inside.  The extra charge varies
from one municipality to another.  The highest extra charge
is 100 percent and the average additional charge is approximately
SO percent.
     There are no revenue figures given in the Kansas report but
using average family water use statistics, it appears that per
capita revenue from residential customers is lower for municipal-
ities that use a flat rate charge than for those local units
that base the charge on water use.
                            MICHIGAN(29)

     The  description of user charges in Michigan is taken from
 a bulletin published by the Michigan Municipal League in 1959.
 It  is  likely  that many of  the municipalities have changed their
 charges in the  last nine years.

     Flat rate  charges are less frequently used in Michigan than
 in  most other States.  Less than six percent of all municipalities
 charge a  flat amount.  Over 85 percent of the local units base
 the charge on water use.   Sixty percent use water volume and
 another 25 percent base the charge on the water bill.  One large
 municipality, Bay City, charges according to the size of the
 water  meter.  The following table presents the distribution of
 charge methods  among municipalities:

                            TABLE  7

                1959 SEWERAGE  CHARGES IN MICHIGAN
                     BY NUMBER OF  LOCAL  UNITS
                                 Basis for Charge	
Population

Over 50,000
25,001-50,000
10,001-25,000
5,001-10,000
2,501-5,000
Under 2,500
      Flat Rate
          3
          2
TOTAL
Source:
Volume of
Water Used

     8
     8
    15
     9
     9
    11

    61
Percentage of
 Water Bill   Other
1
3
2
9
6
5
1

2
1
2

                                  26
Total

 10
 11
 20
 19
 20
 19.

 99
Sewer Service Charges and Related Data in Michigan
Municipalities7 Michigan^fainicipal League, Information
Bulletin No. 91, October 1959.
                             -  70  -

-------
     Nearly all of the municipalities that charge in relation
to water volume have minimum charges.  The minimum charges
are related to meter size much more frequently than in other
States.   The minimum monthly charge for a one family residence
is approximately $1 in most local units.   Although most of
the municipalities have a rate schedule that declines as the
quantity of water increases, flat rate charges per 1,000 gallons
or 100 cubic feet are more common in Michigan than in most
other States.  The flat rate per unit of volume varies from
$.05 to $1.00 for 1,000 cubic feet of water.

     For municipalities charging on  the basis of the water
bill,  the percentage ranges from 40 to 200 percent but most
of the percentages are concentrated  from  40 to 100 percent.
The median is  50 percent.

     Approximately one-half of the municipalities charge a
connection fee.  However, the proportion of local units charging
a fee is not the same in each population category.  Nearly
all of the municipalities with population under 2,500 employ
a charge but most of the local units over 2,500 provide the
service free.  Many have a  variable charge.  The fixed charges
range up to $300.  The median fixed charge is about $90.

     Forty-five municipalities have extra charges for customers
residing outside the municipal boundaries.  The ratio of outside
to inside charges varies a great deal among the municipalities.
Nine charge the regular inside rate, 10 charge 150 percent
and 19 charge 200 percent of the regular rate.  Seven other
local units have different forms of extra charges to outside
customers. Kalamazoo, for example, charges according to property
valuations.


     Several of the municipalities provide adjustments in
the charge for domestic users.  The most common example of
this is the allowance for sprinkling.  Seventeen municipalities
base the charge on the winter water consumption.  Others make
adjustments for air conditioners and water that is not discharged
into sanitary sewers.

     Thirty-one of 82 municipalities require  industries to
pretreat at least some of the wastes.  Twenty-eight of these
local units require pretreatment before the waste can be discharged
into any body of water.  Six municipalities have extra charges
for industrial waste.  The charges are based  on the strength
or concentration of the sewage.
                             -  71  -

-------
     The Michigan report gives some financial data on user
charges and the sewer system.  Data on per capita revenue
from sewer service charges is given for 69 municipalities.
Twenty obtain $7 and above,  25 receive from $4 to $6.99, 17
obtain $2 to $3.99, and 7 receive less than $2.  On the
expenditure side, data on per capita operation and maintenance
costs are given for 57 municipalities.  The cost is $7 or
more for eight municipalities, from $4 to $6.99 for 18 local
units, $2 to $3.99 for 20, and less than $2 for 11 municipalities
Therefore, an average municipality  covers all of the operating
and maintenance costs with sewer service charges and has about
$1 per capita left to cover  debt service charges.  Many
municipalities gave more than one answer to the query about
the purpose of the charges.  The most frequently mentioned
purpose was to provide funds for the operation of the treatment
plant (63 out of 93 municipalities).  This answer was closely
followed by "retire revenue  bonds"  (51 municipalities) and
"operation of sewer systems" (46 municipalities).

     Eighty-five local units also indicated the source of funds
for construction of the sewage treatment system.  Forty-five
issued general obligation bonds and 40 sold revenue bonds.  In
general, the municipalities  over 5,000 population issued
revenue bonds and the local  units under that  size relied on
general obligation bonds.
                           MINNESOTA(30)

      The  description  of  sewerage charges  in Minnesota is taken
 from  a  report written by the League of Minnesota Municipalities
 and Municipal Reference  Bureau.  The report includes information
 obtained  in  a 1965  survey.  The report also compares the results
 of the  1965  survey  and a previous survey  conducted in 1959.

      According  to Minnesota legislation,  municipalities are
 allowed to finance  sewer improvements by  issuing general
 obligation bonds payable from general taxes, special assessments,
 sewage service  charges,  and other non-tax revenues.  The  service
 charges can  be  based  on  the cost of the sewerage service,
 the quantity of water consumed, the quantity and quality of
 the sewage,  a classification of the premises served by the
 system, and  by  any  other equitable basis.  All of the revenue
 received from sewerage charges, sale of sewerage facilities
 or sewage must be placed in a separate fund.  The fund must
Be used first to cover operating and maintenance costs.  Any
revenue remaining may be used to service  the sewerage debt.
                             -  7.2  -

-------
     Minnesota municipalities tend to rely on charges based on
water use more than the municipalities in most States.  Thirty-
four Dercent of the municipalities use a percentage of the
water bill and 20 percent, base the charge on water volume.
Forty-five percent use a flat rate and the remaining one percent
charge according to the size of the water meter.  A table
presenting the distribution of municipalities by charge method
and population size is shown below.
Population

Over 100,000
10,001-100,000
5,001-10,000
2,501-5,000
1,001-2,500
Under 1,000

TOTAL
                           TABLE 8

               1965 SEWERAGE CHARGES IN MINNESOTA
                  BY NUMBER OF MUNICIPALITIES

Flat
Rate

8
1
11
21
22
Bas
Volume of
Water Used
2
9
4
3
7
1
is of Charge
Percentage of
Water Bill

5
9
17
15
6


Other
1

1





Total
3
22
15
25
43
29
62
26
46
136
Source:  Informationfor Municipal Officials:  Sewer Service
         Charges  (sewer rentals) in Minnesota Municipalities,
         League of Minnesota Municipalities and Municipal
         Reference Bureau, Revised December 1965.


     Most of the municipalities that employ a monthly or quarter-
ly flat levy charge a monthly rate between $.50 and $2.50,
Fifty-four of the 62 municipalities are in this range.  The
rate for each unit in multiple-unit dwellings tends to be
lower  than the rate for single family dwellings in most
municipalities.   For example, Columbia Heights charges $1.25
per month for a single family and $.75 for each additional
family.  Approximately 15 of the 62 municipalities change to
a charge based on water use for commercial and industrial
customers.  They  divide about equally between using the water
bill and the volume of water.  These local units  that change
the basis of the  charge are the larger municipalities.  Most of
the smaller municipalities charge the commercial  customers the
same rate as the  residential customers.  Consequently, very few
                             -  73  -
   339-679 O - S9 - 6

-------
 of  the Minnesota municipalities have  the detailed classifications
 of  commercial  establishments  that are found  in many other States.

     For municipalities  employing the percentage of water bill
 method, the percentage ranges  from  25 percent to 140 percent.
 The median rate is  50 percent  but there also is a substantial
 number of local units at 100 percent.

     St. Paul  and Litchfield base the user charge on the size
 of  the water meter.  In  St. Paul, the monthly rate varies from
 $1.50 for a five-eighths inch  meter to $181.20 for a 12 inch
 meter for customers  inside the city.  The rate ranges from $2.50
 to  $298.20 for outside the city.

     There are a few Minnesota municipalities that have sur-
 charges for industrial wastes.  In  the case  of small municipal-
 ities, the surcharge is  related to  a  specific industry.
 Winnebago, Rochester, Duluth,  Owatonna, and  Fergus Falls all
 base the charge on  the volume  and strength of the industrial
 effluent.  Other municipalities such  as Mora and Lake Benton
 have provisions for levying a  special charge on industrial
 wastes.

     The Minnesota  report made some comparisons of its 1959
 and 1965 surveys that give some indication of trends in user
 charges.  Forty percent  of the municipalities made no changes
 in  their sewer rates for residential  customers.  Eighty percent
 of  those municipalities  that  changed  their charges only altered
 the rate and not the basis for the  charge.   The 16 municipal-
 ities that did change charge  formulas are distributed as
 follows:  three changed  from  a flat charge and two from a
 percentage of  the water  bill  to water volume, one changed from
 water volume and eight from a  flat  rate, to  a percentage of the
 water bill and two  changed from percentage of the water bill to
 a flat rate.   This  represents  a net change of 14 from a flat
 rate to a water use  method.   In terms of commercial charges, the
 net change is  13.   The change  from  a  flat rate to a charge based
 on  water use has occurred primarily in larger municipalities
 where there has been an  influx of industry.
                         MISSISSIPPI(31)

     The Mississippi State Board of Health provided the infor-
mation regarding municipal sewer charges in Mississippi for 1965
This report is based on forms filled out by the municipalities
for the State Board of Health.
                             -  74  -

-------
     The most commonly used basis for sewerage charges in
Mississippi is a percentage of the water bill.  This charge
basis is chiefly utilized by the larger municipalities and by
the smaller municipalities in which the commercial and industrial
users are important.  The smaller local units tend to employ a
flat rate charge if the sewer system is primarily used by
residential -customers.  The following table illustrates the
number of municipalities employing each type of charge by
population size.

                            TABLE 9

              1965 SEWERAGE CHARGES IN MISSISSIPPI
                  BY NUMBER OF MUNICIPALITIES

                	Basis for Charge	
                                Percentage of
Population      Flat Rate        Water Rate*        Total

Over 50,000         1                                 1
25,001-50,000       1                 34
10,001-25,000       1                 67
5,001-10,000        3                10              13
2,501-5,000         7                 5              12
1,000-2,500        10                20              30
Under 1,000        l&_                _5_              23^

TOTAL              41                49              90

*There may be some charges based on the quantity of water used
included in the percentage of water bill category.

Source:  Municipal-Residential Sewer Rates, Mississippi State
         Board of Health, 1965.

     The rates charged vary within each category.  Many munici-
palities have a different rate schedule for customers inside the
city than for customers located outside the municipality.  The
outside rate is almost always higher and in some cases no charge
is made to inside customers.  The largest difference appears to
be in Lucedale where insiders are charged an amount equal to
50 percent and outsiders are charged 150 percent of the water
bill.  Also, the charge varies among cities.  The median inside
rate for municipalities employing the percentage of water rate
basis is 33 percent of the water rate but the range is from 5 to
67 percent.  The median flat rate is between $1 and $2 per
month and the range is from zero to $3 for inside customers.
The maximum flat rate for outside customers is also $3.  Several
                             -  75 -

-------
 of the municipalities  have  a maximum amount that can be  levied
 against customers who  are charged  according to their water  bills.
 A common maximum is  $5,00 per month.


                            NEBRASKA(32)

      The information on Nebraska is taken from a survey  published
 by the League of Nebraska municipalities, December 1964.

      Water use is the  most  frequent basis for sewerage charge  in
 municipalities above 500 population.   The smaller cities and
 villages depend almost entirely on a flat monthly charge.
 Although nearly all  of the  first class cities (population 5,000
 or more) levy a service charge almost  a quarter of the smaller
 cities and villages  make no charge for sewage services.   The
 following table describes  the pattern  of charge methods  among
 municipalities.


                             TABLE  10

               1964 SEWERAGE CHARGES IN NEBRASKA
                   BY NUMBER OF MUNICIPALITIES

                 	Basis of  Charge	
                            Volume of  Percentage of
 Population      Flat Rate  Water Use   Water Bill    Total

 Cities
  5,000 $ Over      75            4          16
  Under 5,000      37           2            5          44
 Villages          _5_3_          _2_           _1          55

 TOTAL             97           9            9        115

 Source:   William L.  Wilke Survey of Rates  Charged for
           Electricity,  Water,  Gas,  and Sewerage, The League
           of Nebraska Municipalities in cooperation with
           the Department  of Economics  of the University of
           Nebraska,  December 1964.


     Most of the first class cities employing a  flat charge vary
the charge according to the type of customer.  For example, in
Columbus the monthly rate varies from $1 for residences to $9 for
factories.  York has a $1 charge for residences  and a rate
schedule for business that ranges from $1.10 to  $75.   The
                             -  76  -

-------
municipalities that base the charge on water volume generally have
a minimum charge of $1, and a schedule of rates that declines
with  the quantity of water.  Municipalities that charge in
relation to the water bill levy a monthly charge that ranges from
20 percent of the March water bill to 75 percent of the average
monthly bill for the winter months.  A frequently used value is
50 percent.

      The flat monthly charge used by small cities and villages
ranges from $.35 to $3 per month.  The average charge per month
is about $1.50.


      Nearly one half of all the municipalities in Nebraska tie
some  of the property tax proceeds to financing the sewerage
system.  The villages attach a higher mill rate to sewers than
do the cities.  The mill rate for most of the cities is about
one mill but some of the villages devote six to eight mills.
                       NEW YORK(33)

     The information on user charges in New York is taken from
a report prepared by the New York State Conference of Mayors
and other municipal officials.  The New York report is based on
a questionnaire survey conducted in 1966.  There were 23 cities
and 95 villages that responded to the survey.

     New York municipalities tend to place less emphasis on
sewerage charges than local units in other States.  This
absence of user charges is especially noticeable in cities.
Eight out of 23 cities and 31 out of 95 villages do not levy
service charges.  The cities include Albany, Syracuse, and
Corning,  Another five cities and 19 villages charge only
customers residing outside the municipality.

     Nearly all of the municipalities base the charge on water
use.  Six cities and 21 villages use a percentage of the water
bill.  Three cities and 11 villages base the charge on the volume
of water.  The remaining municipalities levy a flat rate or
base the charge on assessed valuation of the property and the
number and type of fixtures.  One city, Plattsburgh, and 13
villages levy a flat rate.  Three villages and the city of
Buffalo, which uses several charges, base the levy on the
assessed valuation of property.  Four villages that use a flat
rate for residential customers change to water volume for
commercial units.
                            - 77 -

-------
     The percentages used by municipalities that base the
charge on the water bill vary from 25 percent to 100 percent
for cities and 25 percent to 106 percent for villages.  The
median percentage for cities is between 70 and 75 percent and
for villages 50 percent.

     For municipalities that levy a flat rate, the charge per
month ranges from $10 for Geneseo to less than $1 for Waddington.
The median charge is between $4 and $5.

     Basing the user charge on assessed valuation is similar to
using property tax proceeds to cover sewer costs.  Making a
separate charge on property for sewers does, however, indirectly
tie sewer revenues to sewer costs.  The rate varies from one
municipality to another, depending on costs and assessments.
One example, Patchogue, charges a rate of $.99 per $100 of
assessed value.

     New York municipalities tend to charge outside customers
more in relation to inside customers than do the municipalities
in other States.  It is common for outside rates to be twice as
much as inside rates and, occasionally, outside customers are
charged more than three times the amount charged inside
customers.
                       NORTH CAROLINA(34)

     The user charge information for municipalities in North
Carolina is taken from a survey conducted by the North Carolina
League of Municipalities in 1964.  This information is more
limited than for most States, however, because the survey
covered only the municipalities with populations over 10,000.

     Nearly all of the 28 cities included in the survey use a
percentage of the water bill as the basis for the charge.  The
only city with a population over 25,000 that does not use this
method is Asheville, which has no sewerage service charge.  All
of the cities with a population between 10,000 and 25,000 base
the charge on the water bill, except Hickory, which levies a
flat monthly charge.  The percentage of the water charge varies
from 25 percent to 100 percent.  For the cities over 25,000 in
population, the range is 50 percent to 100 percent and the
median is 60 percent.  The range for the cities with populations
between 10,000 and 25,000 is 25 to 75 percent and the median is
40 percent.  The rate for outside customers ranges from 150 to
250 percent of the rate for inside customers.  The typical
outside rate is double the inside rate.
                             -  78  -

-------
     Approximately one quarter of the cities base the minimum
charge directly on the size of the water meter.  Greensboro's
minimum monthly charge which varies from $.85 for a five-eighths
inch meter to $95.55 for an eight inch meter indicates a typical
schedule of rates.

     Most of the cities charge a connection fee that depends on
one or more of these variables:  (1) the size of the pipe;
(2) the condition of the street; and (3) the location of the
customer.  The highest rates are charged to customers who are
located on paved streets outside the city and who require a large
sewer pipe.  A paved street adds from 20 to 100 percent to the
connection charge and a customer will pay from 30 to 80 percent
more if he is located outside the city.  In Fayetteville, for
example, the connection charge for a four inch sewer is $110
inside the city and $150 outside the city.  In Winston Salem
the charge for the same sized sewer is $115 if the street is
paved and $75 if not paved.


                      NORTH DAKOTA(35)

     The information on the sewer service charges levied by
North Dakota municipalities is derived from a bulletin published
by the League of North Dakota Municipalities.  The bulletin
describes the rates that existed March 31, 1963.

     Nearly all of the municipalities with populations over
2,500 base the service charge on water use.  Municipalities
under 2,500 utilize a flat monthly charge.  The distribution
of charge methods by size of municipality is presented in
table 11.

     The municipalities basing the levy on water volume all have
minimum charges.  The minimum charge ranges from $.45 to $2.75
per month for residential customers and from $.50 to $3.25 for
commercial customers.  For local units that use a percentage of
the water bill, the percentage ranges from 10 to 30 percent.

     Nearly all of the municipalities that employ a flat levy
charge a higher rate for commercial customers than for resi-
dential customers.  In many cases, the charge for a commercial
customer depends on the business of the customer.  The charge
for residential, customers range from $.25 to $3 at a monthly
rate.  The median charge is about $1.  For commercial customers,
the range is from $.25 to $25 and the median rate is roughly
equal to $2.  The variation in rates is greater among the
smaller municipalities but the average rate is lower.
                             -  79  -

-------
                            TABLE 11

             1963 SEWERAGE CHARGES IN NORTH DAKOTA BY
                     NUMBER OF MUNICIPALITIES

               	     Basis of Charge	
                            Volume ofPercentage of
 Population    Flat Rate    Water Use    Water Bill     Total

 Over 2,500        2           10
 1,501-2,500      10            3
 1,001-1,500      18            4
 500-1,000
 Under 500

 TOTAL           120           18             5          143

 Source:  Water and Sewerage Rates in North Dakota Cities and
          "Tillages, as of March 1963, League of North Dakota
           Municipalities,Special Bulletin No. 33, July 1963.


                            OHIO(36)

     The summary of user charges in Ohio is based on a 1962
report published by the Ohio Department of Health.  The report
includes material on over 340 municipalities.

     The most common form of sewerage service charge in Ohio
is one based on water volume.  Approximately 50 percent of the
local units base the user charge on the volume of water used.
Most of these municipalities have a schedule of rates that
declines as the quantity of water increases but approximately
10 percent of the local units charge a flat rate per cubic
foot or 1,000 gallons of water.  The remaining 50 percent of
the municipalities are almost evenly divided between a flat
charge and a levy based on the water bill.  Of the municipalities
levying a flat amount per month or quarter, two-thirds charge
the same amount to all customers, and one-third have a rate
schedule that differentiates among various types of property
(e.g. schools,  apartments,  retail stores, etc.).  The following
table illustrates the number of municipalities employing each
charge method.

     The municipalities that base the charge on the water bill
indicate a wider variation in the percentage used than do the
municipalities in most other States.  The range in percentages
                             -  80  -

-------
is from 15 to  200  percent  and the median is between 60 and
70 percent.  For the municipalities  that charge  a flat rate
per unit of volume,  a common charge  is  $.225 per cubic foot.
                               TABLE 12

                     1962 SEWERAGE CHARGES  IN OHIO
                      BY NUMBER  OF MUNICIPALITIES

                   	Basis for  Charge	.
                               Volume ofPercentage  of
  Population      Flat Rate  Water Used   Water Bill     Total

  Over  100,000                     7              18
  10,001-100,000       7          52             28           87
  5,001-10,000         6          31             15           52
  2,501-5,000         14          26             18           58
  1,000-2,500         40          49             20          109
  Under 1,000         1£          12             _5_           53

  TOTAL               83         177             87          347

  Source:   Status  of Sewer  Rental in  Ohio,  Ohio Department  of
            Health,  May 1962.
     All of the municipalities have a minimum or flat charge.  On a
monthly basis this ranges from $.13 to $5.  The median is between $1
and $1.50.

     The primary purpose of the recently created Ohio Water Development
Authority is to aid in financing facilities to control water pollution.
The Authority has the power to acquire, construct, maintain, and operate
water pollution control facilities and make them available to private
industries and municipalities.  These facilities are to be financed
through revenue bonds issued by the Authority. In November 1968, a
$120 million bond issue was passed for water pollution control and
water development (the allocation of funds is to be made by the Assembly).
Revenues used to pay debt service charges and operation costs are to be
based on contracts between the Authority and the participating munici-
palities and industries.

                              OREGON(37)

      The  material  for  Oregon  is  taken  from  a survey conducted
by the Bureau of Municipal Research and Service, University
                                -  81 -

-------
 of Oregon,  in  cooperation with  the League  of Oregon Cities.
 The survey  included  133 cities  and 28 sanitary districts and
 most of  the information was collected for  the year 1964.

      Oregon utilizes charges, special assessments, and property
 tax proceeds to meet the costs  of sewers.  Charges are used
 chiefly  to  meet the costs of treatment plants and to maintain
 the system.  Special assessments are used  in financing sewer
 laterals and the property tax proceeds are often used to retire
 bonds which were issued to provide construction funds.

      Sewerage  charges  came into existence  over 30 years ago in
 Oregon to help meet  the construction and operation and mainte-
 nance costs of sewage  treatment plants.  Periodic surveys have
 indicated a growth in  the use of municipal charges.  There were
 13 cities that used  a  charge in 1942, 102  cities by 1957, and
 currently 127  cities and 25 sanitary districts employ a service
 charge.   There are two cities with populations over 5,000 that
 do not utilize charges.  In many municipalities, one does not,
 in fact, have  to use the sewer  to be subject to the charge.
 In 44 of the cities, all with access to the sewer system are
 charged, and in  61 of  the cities all water users are charged.
 In most  instances, however, water users and those with access
 to the sewer system  are connected to the system.

      Most of the municipalities have separate charge schedules
 for residential  and  commercial  customers.  Thirty-nine
 municipalities used  the same schedule for  two types of customers
 and 88 used separate schedules. Some of the municipalities
 also levy a special  surcharge on industrial waste that is above
 normal strength.  For  example,  Salem's charge is based on volume,
 suspended solids, and  biochemical oxygen demand.

      Over 90 percent of the municipalities employ a flat charge
 for residential customers.  For commercial accounts, flat
 charges  are the commonly used basis, but water use, percent of
 water bill  and type  of business are also extensively used.  The
 table shows the distribution of commercial sewer charges by size
 of municipality and  sanitation  district,   the table also indi-
 cates the number of  local units employing  a special surcharge
 on industrial  sewage of greater than normal strength.

     As   is true of most States,  the larger municipalities tend
to use the volume of water  and a percentage of the water bill as
the basis for a sewerage  charge, and small municipalities base
the charge on a flat rate.   The  table also indicates that the
large municipalities  utilize  a special  surcharge on industrial
waste more than small local units.
                          - 82 -

-------
                                  TABLE 13
     1964 COMMERCIAL SEWER CHARGES IN OREGON BY NUMBER OF MUNICIPALITIES
Population
Over 100,000
25,001 - 100,000
10,001 - 25,000
5,001 - 10,000
2,501 - 5,000
1,001 - 2,500
501 - 1,000
Under 500
Total Cities



Basis
Volume Number
Flat of Water Percent of of
Rate Used Water Bill Fixtures


4
2
4
13
13
8
44
Sanitary Districts* 7
*Many sanitary districts did
Source : Sewage
Policy

4
3
7
3
2
1

20
1
not
System Financing
and Service
1

3
2
5
5
1

17

indicate


1

3
2
2
1
8
1
a charge for
and Service Practices
Practices in
Oregon Cities
for Charge


Special Surcharge
Type for
of Industrial
Business Other Total Sewage



1
3
7
9
1
21
1
1
4
11
11
2 20
1 30
2 28
10
5 115
10
1
3
1
1
1



7
2
commercial units .
: A Survey of
and Sanitary
Sewage Rates ,
Financing
Districts, Bureau of
Municipal Research and Service, University of Oregon in cooperation with League of
Oregon Cities, Information Bulletin No. 155, 1960.

-------
     All municipalities employing a charge have a minimum for
residences.  This charge ranges from $.25 to $5 per month.  The
minimum charge has increased over time.  The median charge was
$.75 in 1952, $1 in 1967 and rose to $1.75 in 1964.

     Most cities charge a connection and/or a permit fee when
the sewer connection is authorized.  The permit fee is used to
meet the cost of inspection.  The connection charge is often
used to offset the cost of the connection to the city.  Over
70 cities and 11 sanitary districts charge a connection fee.
The connection fee for cities ranges from under $20 to over
$400, and the median is a little less than $100 for cities
and approximately $250 for sanitary districts.

     The revenue from sewerage charges is substantial in most
local units.  Portland obtained over $2 million and Eugene and
Salem each received over $500,000 in 1964.  Many of the
municipalities in the 10,000-25,000 range of population obtained
over $100,000.  In per capita terms the high was the $46.65
obtained in Cannon Beach, and over 26 cities received more
than $10, The per capita yield was between five and six dollars
for most of the population groups in the table.  Much of this
revenue goes toward retiring bonds which were issued to obtain
funds for the construction of the sewers and sewage treatment
plants. In 1964 approximately 44 percent of the funds used
for debt service funds came from sewerage charges.  Debt service
charges will be at a high level over a period of years because
over 45 cities issued bonds for sewers and treatment plants
in the 1959-64 period.


                       SOUTH DAKOTA(38)

     The information on South Dakota is drawn from reports
publiished by the University of South Dakota and the South
Dakota Department of Health, in cooperation with the South
Dakota Municipal League.  The most recent report is based on a
survey conducted in 1967.  However, this report does not include
any information on the revenue raised by service charges for
cities under 500 population and these data are based on a
1964 survey.

     Approximately one-third of the municipalities in the State
do not have any sewerage service charges.  Although most of these
municipalities have populations of less than 500, some large
cities including Aberdeen and Rapid City, have no sewage service
charges.  Nearly all of the first class cities (population
exceeds 5,000) base the user charge on a percentage of the water
                            - 84 -

-------
bill but the most commonly used charge in South Dakota is the
flat monthly charge.  Approximately one-sixth of the municipal-
ities employing a flat charge vary the charge by type of
customer.  For example. Lake Norden charges residences $1 and a
creamery at a rate of $90 per month.  Some of the municipalities
that levy a flat charge on residential customers base the charge
for commercial and industrial customers on water use.  The
following table illustrates the type of charges employed by
South Dakota municipalities.

                            TABLE 14

1967  SEWERAGE  CHARGES IN SOUTH DAKOTA BY NUMBER OF MUNICIPALITIES

                	Basis for Charge	

                           Volume of   Percentage of
Population      Flat Rate  Water Used  Water Bill     Total

5,000 and over      116            8

500 - 4,999        34           57           46

Under 500          15          _1         	           16

  TOTAL            50           7         13           70

Source:  Wastewater Facilities in South Dakota Municipalities,
         Statewide EducationalServices,The University of
         South Dakota, in cooperation with the Department of
         Health.  Report No 767, August 1967.

     For the first class cities that base the charge on a
percentage of the water bill, the percentage ranges from 35
percent to 100 percent of the average winter bill.  Many of
the muncipalities charging a flat rate base the charge on
a quarter rather than a month.  On a monthly basis, however,
the charge ranges from $.33 to nearly $4.  Most of the
charges fall between $.50 and $1 per month.

     The first class cities that employ user charges received
between $33,000 and $78,000 in 1966.S/ In per capita terms,
most of the cities obtained approximately $7.  In nearly all
cases, the municipalities believed that the yield was adequate

 i/
  Sioux Falls did not begin its system of charges until
  after 1966.
                            - 85 -

-------
in terms of meeting costs.   For municipalities with population
between 500 and 5000, the per capita yield varies greatly.
Some municipalities obtain only about $1 per person.  At
the  opposite end of the scale Mission receives $20.  Wall
receives more than $13 and Moonsocket more than $12.  The
median yield is approximately $5.

     The per capita yield for municipalities with populations
below 500 ranges from $2 to over $20 with the median about
$4.  The municipalities that receive a high yield judge it
to be adequate to cover costs but most of the local units
receiving a low yield view the revenue as inadequate.

     Some of the municipalities have issued revenue bonds
to provide construction funds.  These bonds are retired
through the revenue obtained from the service charges.
This method of financing sewerage systems has been used
more by the smaller municipalities than by the larger cities.
Although Sioux Falls expects to cover its construction costs
with the newly instituted system of charges, most of the first
class cities expect to rely on assessment and general obligation
bonds.
                            TENNESSEE(34)

     The description of sewerage charges in Tennessee is based on
a 1967 report by the Tennessee State Planning Commission.

     The report covers utility districts -as well as munici-
palities.  It is estimated that there are 180 utility districts
in the State.  They range in size from those serving 60 people
to those serving many thousands.  Most of them, however, do not
appear to levy sewerage charges.

     The most commonly used basis for service charges in
Tennessee municipalities is a percentage of the water bill.
Approximately 60 percent of the local units use this charge
method.  The next most popular method is a flat charge.  Over
20 percent of the municipalities employ this form of user charge
and the remainder base the charge on the volume of water.  The
following table illustrates the use of each method by size of the
local unit.

     The range'in percentages for municipalities that charge on
the basis of the water bill is from 10 to 100 percent.  The
median percentage is 50 percent.  In general, large municipal-
ities charge a higher percentage than do small local units.
                             - 86 -

-------
 Gatllnburg has  an unusual  charge scheme  in  that the percentage
 applied to the  water bill  rises as the amount of the bill
 increases.
 ranges
For municipalities  employing a flat  monthly charge,  the levy
s from  $.50 to $5.  The median charge is approximately $2.
                               TABLE 15


                   1967  SEWERAGE CHARGES IN TENNESSEE
                        BY NUMBER OF LOCAL UNITS
                                       Charge Basis
   Population

   Over 40,000

   15,001-40,000

   10,001-15,000

   5,001 -10,000

   3,001 - 5,000

   1,000 - 3,000

   Under 1,000

   Utility Districts*

   Total
Flat Rate

1
1
1
3
8
9
5
28
Volume of
Water Used
2
4
1
5
3
5
3
3
26
Percentage of
Water Bill

6
10
14
14
26
6
4
80
Total
2
11
12
20
20
39
18
12
134
   * These vary in size

   Source:  Sanitary Services in Tennessee 1967, Tennessee State Planning
           Commission, Nashville, November 1967.


     The municipalities  basing the  charge on volume of water  all
have minimum charges  and a schedule of rates that declines as the
quantity of water increases.  The minimum charge is between
$1 and  $2  in most cases.
                              - 87  -

-------
      The majority  of  the Tennessee municipalities  levy  a  tap  or
 connection  fee  but many of  the  smaller municipalities appear
 to  provide  this  service free of charge.  The Nashville-Dawson
 County Metropolitan Government  charges from $3  for a four inch
 sewer to $1,000  for a  12 inch sewer, but nearly all of  the
 municipalities  charge  $100  or less.

      The revenue yield from user charges is given  for some
 of  the municipalities  in the Tennessee report.   Several other
 local units show a combined water-sewerage figure.  Over
 two-thirds of the  local units obtain a per-capita  yield of
 between $8  and  $13.  There  are, however, some local units that
 are well outside this  range,  A few municipalities obtain less
 than  $1 and Gatlinburg obtains  over $50 per person.


                             TEXAS(40)

      The information  on user charges in Texas is based  on a 1967
 report published by the Texas Municipal League. The League
 report summarizes  data obtained from a survey of 357
 municipalities.

      Many of the Texas municipalities charge commercial and
 industrial  customers  according  to a formula that is different
 from  the formula used  for residential customers.  For
 residential customers  52 percent of the municipalaties  employ
 a flat rate.  Another  40 percent base the  levy  on  the number
 of  fixtures and less  than eight percent charge  in  relation to
 water use.  Flat rates and  charges in relation  to  the number
 of  fixtures are  less  commonly used, and charges based on  water
 use are more commonly  used  in assessing commercial and  industrial
 customers.  Thirty-nine percent of the municipalities base
 commercial  charges on  the number of fixtures.   Twenty four per-
 cent  charge in  relation to  water use, 22 percent levy flat rates
 and another 12  percent levy a flat rate that varies with  the
 type  of business.  The remaining three percent  of  the local
 units charge on  the basis of number of taps or  number of
 employees.  The  following table presents the number of  municipal-
 ities using each form  of charge for commercial  and residential
 customers.

     The range in  flat monthly charges  for residential customers
is from $.50 in Junction to $3.15 in Port Neeches.   The median
charge for the 184 municipalities is $1.50 per month.   Nearly
one-half of these municipalities service customers who reside
outside the city.  The ratio of inside to outside  charges varies
from one municipality to another.   Many municipalities levy
                            - 88 -

-------
                               TABLE 16
       1967 SEWERAGE CHARGES IN TEXAS BY NUMBER OF MUNICIPALITIES
                              Residential
Population




Over 25,000




10,001 - 25,000




 5,000 - 10,000




Under 5,000




Total
Population




Over 25,000




10,001 - 25,000




 5,000 - 10,000




Under 5,000




Total

Flat
Rate
14
32
28
110
184

Number of
Fixtures
17
24
41
60
142
Basis
Water
Volume
11
7
1
_2
21
for the Charge
Percentage of
Water Bill Other
1

1 1
!_ _
3 1

Total
43
63
72
173
351
Commercial*

Flat
Rate
1
6
13
55
75
immercia]
Service

Number of
Fixtures
13
23
38
56
130
L schedule
Basis
Water
Volume
20
18
12
13
63
for the Charge
Percentage of
Water Bill Other
6 2
7 7
3 3
3 34
19 46

Total
42
61
69
161
333
or unknown - 18 cities
in Texas Cities , Texas Municipal League ,
Austin
         December  1967,  P.Viii.
                                 - 89  -
   339-679 O - 69 - T

-------
the same charge against both inside and outside customers and
the outside rate is less than double the inside rate for nearly
all municipalities.  One exception is El Paso, which charges
$1.50 to inside customers and $6.50 to customers residing outside
the city.  The monthly rates levied against commercial customers
range from $.25 in Fayettsville to $10 in Windcrest.  The median
charge is $2.50 and the most common charge is $1.50.  The range
is greatest for the municipalities under 5,000 population but
the median for this category is the same as the median for all
municipalities.

     In addition to the 75 municipalities that charge the same
rate to all commercial customers, there are 41 local units
that vary the charge by the type of commercial customer.  Most
of these municipalities are in the smallest population category.
The local units generally have from three to seven categories
of establishments.  The charges do not generally exceed $10
a month for any category except schools and hospitals.  Charges
for these two categories range up to $25 and $30 in some
municipalities.


     All of the municipalities that base the charge to
residential customers on water use have a minimum levy.  The
minimum ranges from $.30 to $2 a month.  The variable charge
takes one of three forms.  The most common form is a rate
schedule where the rate for additional units of water decreases
as the quantity of water increases.  A second form is a
percentage of the water bill.  The third form of charge is a
combined water and sewerage charge.  This third form of charge
is used in Austin but is not common.  The three municipalities
that charge on the basis of the water bill use three different
percentages  (25, 50, and 75 percent).


     Most of the local units that charge commercial and
industrial establishments according to water use also have
minimum charges.  A few of the large municipalities base
the charge on the size of the water meter.  In Fort Worth the
minimum monthly charge ranges from $.90 for a five-eighths
or three-fourths inch meter to $106 for a 10 inch meter.
The precentage used by municipalities that base the charge
on the Water bill ranges from 5 to 80 percent but nearly all
the local units use 40 percent or less.


     The charge by municipalities that base the levy on water
use ranges from $.50 to $4.05 for 5,000 gallons.  The median
charge is between $1.50 and $2.
                             -  90  -

-------
     All of the municipalities that base residential and
commercial charges on the number of fixtures have a minimum
monthly charge.  The minimum charge for residential customers
ranges from $.10 for one fixture in Coleman to $3 for five
fixtures in Commerce.  The commercial minimum ranges from
$.10 to $4.  The rate ranges between $.10 and $1 for each
fixture above the number included in the minimum.  For four
fixtures, the .charge ranges from $.50 to $4.75 to residential
customers and $.55 to $6 for commercial establishments.  The
residential median is approximately $1.50 and the commercial
median $2.

     Two municipalities charge commercial customers according
to the number of employees and three charge on the basis of
the number of taps.  Commerce charges $,30 for each two
employees, Sulphur Springs charges $.50 for each tap over two
and Hughes Springs charges $3 for each tap.

     A  few of  the  municipalities have a  special  charge  for
industries.  The charge varies by  type of  industry  rather
than by any measure  of the strength of the effluent.   For
example,  Waco  charges a higher percentage  of  the water  bill
to packing, poultry, and milk plants than  to  laundries  and
bottling works.  Most municipalities do  have  ordinances  that
regulate the wastes  that can be discharged into  the sewer
system.   In addition to regulations on specific wastes,  some
municipalities  limit the concentration of  grease, suspended
solids,  and biochemical oxygen demand.   Fifty four  or  15
percent  of the  local units require pretreatment  of  industrial
wastes.

     Most of  the municipalities have fees  for permits  and
sewer  connections.   Fifty-two local units  charge a  flat
plumbing permit fee  and  185  levy a fee that depends on  the
number  of fixtures.  The flat fees range from $.50  to  $20
and the median is  between  $2.50 and $4.  In municipalities
where  the number of  fixtures  enter into  the fee, the charge
ranges  from  $,75 to  $13  for  four fixtures  and $1.35 to  $24
for 12  fixtures.   The tap  fee is based on  the actual cost
in some  municipalities.  The  flat  rate charges  range from
$0 to  $85.

     The reported  revenue  obtained from  user  charges ranged
from over $6 million for Dallas to less  than  $1,000 in  some
municipalities.  In  over 90  percent of the municipalities,
the revenue from user charges was  greater  than  the  operating
and maintenance costs of collection and  treatment.  In  Dallas,
                             - 91 -

-------
the revenue was three times the costs and in some municipal-
ities the ratio of revenue to operating and maintenance  costs
was greater than two to one.  The per capita yield ranged
from less than $1 to over $30 but most of the municipalities
obtained between $5 and $8 per person.

     The Texas Report includes the monthly charge levied
by 36 municipalities on four dates:  1939, 1950,  1960,1967.
The  charge  is  for  5,000 gallons per month.  The  high, low
and  median  rates are shown  for each year in the  following
table.

                        TABLE 17

             MONTHLY SEWER  SERVICE CHARGES BY YEARS IN
                     TEXAS MUNICIPALITIES
Year
1939
1.50
.50
0
0
1950
1.50
1.00
0
1.00
1960
$2.00
1.0.0
0
1.00
1967
$2.25
1.25
.68
1.00
High

Median

Low

Most common charge

Source:  Sewer Service in Texas Cities, Texas Municipal League,
         Austin, December 1967, Page Vi and Vii.

The table shows that rates have moved steadily upwards.  In
1939 only three local units charged more than $1 and 13 had
no charge.  In 1967 all levied a charge and over twenty charged
more than $1.  The table does not indicate, however, whether
rates have risen as fast as costs.


                            VIRGINIA(41)

     The material on Virginia is taken from a report by the
Virginia Municipal League.  The information in the report is
based on a survey of towns conducted by the League in 1963.

     The most commonly used basis for sewer service charges In
Virginia towns is a percentage of the water bill.  For the 50
towns surveyed, 19 used a percentage of the water bill, 11 used
                             - 92  -

-------
a flat monthly charge, 8 used water volume, 1 charged in relation
to the number of fixtures, and 11 had no sewer service charge.

     For municipalities that charge in relation to the water
bill, the percentage ranges from 20 to 100 percent, and the
median is 50 percent.  Some of these municipalities also levy a
minimum charge.  The minimum charge does not exceed $2 per
month for any residential customer inside the municipality.

     The range for flat rates is $.50 to $2 and the median rate
is $1.25.  The towns basing the charge on water volume are
almost evenly divided between charging a fixed rate per thousand
gallons and a declining rate.  A typical fixed charge is  $.15
per  thousand gallons.

     The Virginia towns also charge a sewer connection fee.  The
charge varies from $5 if  labor and material are supplied by the
customer or $15 if supplied by the town, to $300.  The median
fee  is in the $75-$100 range.

     Some of the municipalities levy a higher connection fee
and  service charge on customers outside the city.  This
additional charge averages about 33 percent in most cases.

     The League study did not include the  larger municipalities
in its survey.  However,  some information  on these larger
municipalities can be gleamed from other sources.  For example,
Richmond, Roanoke, Harrisonburg, Martinsville, Virginia Beach,
and Wythevilleuse the volume of water or water bill as the basis
for  their charges.  Alexandria, Pulaski, and Winchester use a
flat monthly charge,


                            WASHINGTON

     The material on  sewerage charges in Washington is taken
from a 1964 bulletin  published by the University of Washington.
The  bulletin was sponsored by the Association of Washington
Cities in cooperation with the Bureau of Governmental Research
and  Services.

     In  general, municipalities  in Washington finance lateral
extensions through local  improvement districts, major trunk
lines by a general tax  levy or a general obligation bond issue,
and  treatment  and disposal facilities by revenue bonds.  The
operation and maintenance costs  are covered primarily by service
and  connection charges.   This financing system is  an attempt
to connect local charges  with expenditures that yield primarily
                             -  93 -

-------
local benefits, and general charges with the benefits that are
essentially general in nature.  In keeping with this philosophy,
municipalities are allowed to charge a lower rate in areas where
the system has been fully amortized than in areas where
extensions are being made.

     Many of the large municipalities base the user charge on
volume of water but the predominant method employed in Washington
is a flat monthly charge.  Nearly all of the municipalities vary
the charge by the number of units in the dwelling.  In some
cases, the rate per unit is constant and in others it declines
after the first unit.  Approximately six of the municipalities
charge a flat rate to single family dwellings but shift to
volume of water for dwellings with multiple units.  The monthly
charge for a single family residence within the city ranges from
$.75 to $5, but nearly all of the municipalities charge between
$1 and $3.

     The municipalities that charge a flat rate to commercial
and industrial customers generally have a detailed schedule of
rates.  Richland for example has 12 classifications.  In
addition, some categories like restaurants are further classified
according to the number of seats.  The monthly charge ranges
from $2 for churches, clubs and garages, to $25 for some
hotels and motels.  The highest rate in most municipalities is
charged to schools.  In a small number of local units, the
charge is based on average daily attendance.

     The municipalities  that  charge  in  relation  to water volume
have a minimum charge and a rate schedule that declines with the
quantity of water used.  The  minimum is approximately $200
for most municipalities.  For local  units that employ a
percentage of the water  as the method of charging users, the
percentage ranges from 35 percent  to 80 percent  and  the median
is 75 percent.  Spokane  and Bellingham base their charge on
the size of the water meter.  In Bellingham the monthly charge
ranges from $1.50 for a  three-fourths inch meter to  $48 for
a  24 inch meter.  The following table indicates  the number
of municipalities employing each charge method, by size of
municipality.

     Nearly all of the local  units charge customers residing
outside the municipality more than the inside customers.  The
amount of the additional levy varies among municipalities but
the most common formula  employed is  a 50 percent surcharge on
outside customers.

     Municipalities  in Washington  tend to employ variable
connection charges more  than  municipalities in other States.
                             -  94 -

-------
Seattle and many other local units make a charge that is equal
to the actual cost of the connection and other municipalities
charge in relation to number of front feet.  Takoma, for
example, charges $4.50 per front feet (minimum charge $225).


                           TABLE 18

            1964 Sewerage Charges in Washington by
                    Number of Municipalities

                         Basis of Charge

                                             ——Size of
                           Volume of Percentage of  Water
Population      Flat Rate  Water Use Water Bill	Meter  Total

Over 100,000                   2                      13
10,001-100,000     9           33           1       16
 5,001- 10,000     31                              4
 2,501-  5,000     833                  14
 1,000-  2,500    17                                         17
Under 1,000       12                                         12

Total	49	9	6	2	66

SOURCE:  David W. Stevens and Richard A Cornils, Sewer Rates in
         Washington Cities, Association of Washington Cities
         in Cooperation with the Bureau of Government Research
         and Services, Univ., of Wash., Seattle, Inf., Bui.
         No. 263, November 1964.
                             WISCONSIN

      The description of  user charges  in Wisconsin  is  based  on
 a summary of sewer  service charges  published by the Wisconsin
 Department of Natural Resources,  dated July  1963.

      Over two-thirds of  the municipalities in Wisconsin base
 the charge on a percentage of the water bill.   For the
 municipalities with a population  that exceed 1,000, over 80 percent
 charge in relation  to the  water bill.  Although the percentage
 ranges from 25 percent to  300 percent, most  of the municipal-
 ities are concentrated around 100 percent.   A large majority
 of the municipalities base the charge on the average  of the
 winter bills or make allowance for  sprinkling.
                             - 95 -

-------
     Approximately 25 percent of the municipalities base the
user charge on a flat rate.  These local units tend to vary
the residential rate by the number of housing units in a
dwelling.  For example, Brookfield charges a monthly rate
(most Wisconsin municipalities charge by the quarter) of
$4 for a single family and $4 for each additional unit.  The
rates range from less than $1 to nearly $5 at a monthly rate.
The median charge is approximately $3 for a single dwelling.
Many municipalities employing a flat charge have a very
detailed schedule of rates for commercial customers.  The
community of Osceola has nine categories and rates range
from $.50 per month for churches to $25 for hotel and
$35 for a school.  A typical municipality has five categories
and the rates range from $3 to $10.  The highest charge is
generally assessed against a school or hospital.  In some
municipalities this charge exceeds $100 per month.  Another
variation of the fixed charge is found in Wisconsin.  In
some municipalities the commercial charge is based on both
the type of establishment and the number of employees.  Nearly
all the municipalities employ either the flat rate or percentage
of the water bill methods.  However, a few municipalities base
the charge on water volume, size of water meter and number
of connections.  One variation is a minimum charge based
on the size of the water meter combined with a variable charge
which is related to the volume of water used.  For example,
Baldwin's minimum ranges from $1.67 (monthly rate) for
a 5/8" meter to $28.33 for a 4" meter.  The variable charge
is from $.10 to $.45 per thousand gallons.

     The following table indicates the number of municipal-
ities employing each type of charge.  The table is based on
the charge made to residential customers.  The charge to
commercial customers is on the same basis as for residential
users in most municipalities.  The major difference between
commercial and residential users is that the monthly charges
are higher and there are more rate categories for commercial
customers.

     Approximately one-third of the Wisconsin municipalities
have special charges for industrial wastes.   A few of the
local units employ general charges but most municipalities
tailor the charge to the specific industry that is connected
to the municipal system.  The general formulas take the
form of a charge per employee as in Maxomanie, a charge per
pound of biochemical oxygen demand, as in Fontana, or a charge
base'd on an effluent of greater than normal strength as in
Madison.  In municipalities where the charge is tailored to
an industry, the levy may be a flat rate, or it may be based on
                             - 96  -

-------
water use,  number of employees,  or output.   In  Broadhead,
cheese factories are assessed $100, cheese packing plants
$50, and  industries that  discharge sanitary  effluents only
$25.  Bertin charges a tanning company by the volume of water
used, a brewing company by  the number of barrels  of beer
produced,  and a canning company a flat rate  plus  a percentage
of the water bill.

     Virtually no information on revenue is  given in the
Wisconsin summary.  However,  since the most  common charge
method is a percentage of the water bill and since the
average percentage is higher  than for most cities, it is
likely that the per capita  revenue from sewer charges is
higher in Wisconsin than  in most other states.
                             TABLE 19

                 1963 SEWERAGE CHARGES IN WISCONSIN BY
                      NUMBER OF MUNICIPALITIES
  Population

  Over 100,000
  10,001 - 100,000
   5,001 -  10,000
   2,501 -   5,000
   1,001 -   2,500
  Under 1,000

  Total
Flat  Rate

   1
    3
   11
   27

   42
  Basis of Charge

Percentage of
 Water Bill

     1
     8
     14
     22
     41
     30
    116
Other
  2
  1
  1
  6
 11
Total

   1
  11
  15
  26
  58
  58
 169
  Source:  Summary of_ Sewer Service Charge in Wisconsin,  July 1963,
          Wisconsin Department of Natural Resources, Division of
          Environmental Projection, 1963.
                              - 97 -

-------
                        REFERENCES CITED


 1.  Break, George F., Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations in the
     United States.  The Brookings Institution, Washington,B.C.,
     1967.

 2.  Maxwell, James A., Financing State and Local Governments,
     The Brookings Institution, Washington, B.C., 1965.

 3.  Revenue Sharing and its Alternatives:  What Future Fiscal
     Federalism?Prepared for the Subcommittee on Fiscal Policy
     of the Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United
     States, 90th Congress, 1st Session, Washington, B.C.,
     July 1967.

 4.  Harris, C. Lowell (ed.)  Federal-State-Local Fiscal
     Relationships. Tax Insitute of America, Princeton,
     New Jersey, 1968.

 5.  Unshackling Local Government, Revised ed. , 24th Report by
     the Committee on Government Operation, House Report 1270,
     90th Congress, 2nd Session, Washington, B.C., April 1968.

 6.  Johnson, Lyndon B., Conservation and Water Manage-
     ment - Message f rom tHe President of the United°St~ates,
     House Document No. 273, 90th Congress, 2nd Session,
     Washington, B.C., March 1968.

 7.  Guide Lines for Drafting a Municipal Ordinance on In-
     dustrial-Waste Regulations and Surcharges,American
     Public Works Association, Special Report No. 23,
     Chicago, 1959.

 8.  Imbelli, Charles Pressman, William B., Radiloff, Harold.
     "The Industrial Wastes Control Program in New York City."
     Paper - New York State Water Pollution Control Association,
     January 1966.

 9.  Smalla, R. Bean,  "One Way to Control Wastes,"
     Water and Wastes Engineering, Vol. 4, No. 3, 1967.

10.  Bubbis, N.S., "Industrial Waste Control in Metropolitan
     Winnipeg," Journal of Water Pollution Control Federation,
     Nov. 1963.

11.  Symons, James M., "Rate Formulas for Industrial Wastes,"
     Water and Sewage Works, Becember 1954.
                            - 98 -

-------
12.  Taylor, Dean M., "Industrial Waste Ordinances - Parts I
     and II," Water Sewage Works, August and October 1956.

13.  Fisher, C. E., "Cincinnati Industry Reduces Sewer Surcharges,"
     Sewage and Industrial Wastes, Volume 28, No. 9, 1956.

14.  Division of Water Pollution Control, Information,
     Ordinances, Rules and Regulations of the Metropolitan
     Sewage Disposal System^Cincinnati, January 21. 1953-
     Juhe 1, 1962,

15.  Division of Water Pollution Control, Reports on Water
     Pollution Control, 1964 through 1968.City of Cincinnati.

16.  Bureau of the Census.  City Government Finances in 1965-66.
     U.S. Department of Commerce, Washington, D.C.,  July 1967.

17.  Federal Water Pollution Control Administration,  Water and
     Sewer Bond Sales in the United States, Jan.-Dec. 1967"^
     Department of the Interior, Washington, D.  C.

18.  Federal Water Pollution Control Administration,  The Cost of
     Clean Water, U. S. Department of the Interior, Washington,
     D. C., January 1968.

19.  Moak, Lennox L., Sewer Service Charges, Municipal Finance
     Officers Association of the United States and Canada,
     Chicago, 1962.

20.  U, S. Congress, Senate, Committee on Public Works,
     Hearings Before a Special  Subcommittee on Air and Water
     Pollution, Part I,,  90th Congress, 2nd Session,
     Washington, D. C., March 27, 1968.

 21.   Industrial Waste Disposal  Charges in Cities Over 5,000
      PopulationTAmerican Public Works Association, Special
      Report No. 18, Chicago, 1955.

22.  Sewage Service Charges  in  Cities over  5,000,  American
     Public Works Association,  Special Report No. 18,
     Chicago  1955.

23.  A Summary  of Municipal Water and Sewer Rates, State  of
     Alabama  Water  Improvement  Commission, Montgomery,1961.

24.  Sewer Rates:  Municipal Utility Rate  Survey,  Florida
     League of Municipalities,  Jacksonville, 1967.
                             - 99 -

-------
25.  A Study of Municipal Water and Sewer Utility Rates and
     Practices in Georgia^Georgia Municipal Association,
     Atlanta, 1965.

26.  Idaho Water and Sewer Rates, Idaho Municipal League,
     January 1966.

27.  Sewer Rental Ordinances in Iowa Cities and Towns,Iowa
     State Department of Health, Des Moines, 1959.

28.  Sewage Service Charges in Kansas Cities,  League of Kansas
     Municipalities, Topeka, June 1968.

29.  Sewer Service Charges and Related Data in Michigan
     Municipalitie's^  Michigan Municipal League, Information
     Bulletin No. 91, Ann Arbor, October 1959.

30.  Information for Municipal Officials:  Sewer Service
     Charges  (Sewer Rental's) in Minnesota Municipalities,
     League of Minnesota Municipalities and Municipal
     Reference Bureau, Minneapolis, December 1965.
31.
Municipal - Residential Sewer Rates,  Mississippi
State Board of Health, Jackson, 1965.
32.  Wilke, William L., Survey of Rates Charged for Electricity,
     Water, Gas, and Sewerage.The League of Nebraska
     Municipalities in Cooperation with the Department of
     Economics, University of Nebraska, December 1964.

33.  Sewer Service Charges and Sewer Charge Billing Procedures
     in New York State Cities and Villages, New York State
     Conference of Mayors and Other Municipal Officers, Report
     No. 66-13, Albany, 1966.

34.  Water and Sewer Service Charges in North Carolina
     Municipalities Over 10.000 Population as of September 1964,
     North Carolina League of Municipalities, Report No. 100,
     Raleigh, September 1964.

35.  Water and Sewerage Rates in North Dakota Cities and
     Villages, as of March 1963":  League of North Dakota
     Municipalities, Special Bulletin No. 33, Bismarck,
     July 1963.

36.  Status of Sewer Rental in Ohio,  Ohio Department of
     Health, May
                            - 100 -

-------
37.   Sewage System Financing and Service Practices:   A
     Survey- of Sewerage Rates, Financing Policies and Service
     Practices in Oregon Cities and Sanitary Districts^Bureau
     of Municipal Research and Service, University or Oregon
     in Cooperation with the League of Oregon Cities,
     Information Bulletin No. 155, Eugene, 1960.

38.   Wastewater Facilities in South Dakota. Municipalities,
     Statewide Education Services, the University of South
     Dakota, in Cooperation with the South Dakota Municipal
     League and the State Department of Health,  Report No.767,
     Vermillion, 1967.  Sewer Facilities Data in South Dakota
     Cities and Towns,   The Extension Division,  University of
     South Dakota,in Cooperation with the South Dakota Municipal
     League, Vermillion, 1965.

39.   Sanitary Services in Tennessee 1967, Tennessee State
     Planning Commission, Nashville, November 1967.

40.   Sewer Service in Texas Cities,  Texas Municipal League,
     Austin, December 1967.

41.   Sewer Charges in Virginia Towns,  Virginia Municipal
     League, Richmond, 1963.

42.   Stevens, David W. , and Cornils, Richard A., Sewer Rates in
     Washington Cities.  Association of Washington Cities in
     Cooperation with the Bureau of Government Research and
     Services, University of Washington, Information Bulletin
     No. 263, Seattle, November, 1964.

43.   Summary of Sewer Service Charges in Wisconsin,  July 1963.
     Wisconsin Department of Natural Resources,  Division of
     Environmental Projection, Madison, July 1963.

44.   Due, John F.  Government Finance:  Economics of the Public
     Sector, Fourth Edition. Richard D. Irwin, 1968,
     Homewood, Illinois.

45.   Berber, Bernard,  Modern Public Finance,   Homewood,
     Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, 1907.

46.   St. Clair, G. P. "Suggested Approaches to the Problems
     of Taxation."  Paper supplied by U. S. Department of
     Public Roads, Proceedings, 27th Annual Meeting of the
     Highway Rearch Board, Washington,  1947.

47.  Joint  Report  of  Committees of the  American  Society  of
     Civil  Engineers,  Section of Municipal  Law of the
                            - 101 -

-------
     American Bar Association and Representatives of Six
     Other Groups,  "Fundamental Considerations in Rates
     and Rate Structures for Water and Sewage."  Ohio
     State Law Journal,   Spring, 1961.

48.  Smith, Robert,   Preliminary Design and Simulation of
     Conventional Wastewater Renovation Systems Using the
     the Digital Computer,Federal Water Pollution Control
     Administration, U.  S.  Department of the Interior,
     Cincinnati, 1968.

49.  Frankel, R. J.  Economic Evaluation of Water Quality,
     Sanitary Engineering Research Laboratory, University
     of California,  Berkely, SERLR Report No.  653, 1965.

50.  American Public Works  Association, Problems of Combined
     Sewer Facilities and Overflows,  Prepared for the
     Federal Water Pollution Control Administration, U, S.
     Department of the Interior, December, 1967.

51.  ABT Associates, Incentives to Industry for Water Pollution
     Control: Policy Considerations,Prepared for the Federal
     Water Pollution Control Administration, U. S. Department
     of the Interior, 1967.

52.  Walter, C. Richard.  "Determination of Charges and
     Surcharges for Waste Treatment."  Paper presented at
     the 34th Annual Meeting of the New York Water Pollution
     Control Association, New York City, January 1962.

53.  Zettel, Richard M.  "Objectives and Concepts of Highway
     User Taxation," Highway User Taxation, Highway Research
     Board Bulletin No.  92, Washington, D. C., 1954 Pp. 1-14.

54.  Musgrave, R. A. The Theory of Public Finance,  New York:
     McGraw-Hill, 1959.

55.  Newman, Herbert E., An Introduction to Public Finance,
     John Wiley and Sons, New York, 1968.

56.  Johnson, J. A. The Incidence of Government Revenue and
     Expenditure Programs,Ontario Committee on Taxation,
     Toronto, 1968.

57.  Howarth, Don,  The Federal Water Pollution Control Program:
     A Case Study of"Two New England Towns,ABA Thesis
     sponsored by the Harvard Water Program, Harvard University,
     1968.
                            - 102 -

-------
58.   Bureau of the Census,  Census of Manfactures, 1963,
     Vol.  1-3, U. S.  Department of Commerce, Washington,
     D.  C., 1966,

59.   Wolf,  Jerome B.  and Linaweaver, F. P. Jr., Report on The
     Commercial Water Use Research Project,  Environmental
     Engineering Science, John Hopkins University, Baltimore,
     June  1966.

60.   Unpublished Material Supplied by Hittman, Associates,
     Inc.  Columbia, Maryland.

61.   Unpublished Material Supplied by the Baltimore Department
     of Assessment, Baltimore, Maryland.

62.   Unpublished Material Supplied by FWPCA, Ohio Basin
     Region, Cincinnati, Ohio.

63.   U.  S.  Bureau of the Census, Annual Survey of Manufactures,
     1964,  Book Value of Fixed Assets and Rental Payments for
     Buildings and Equipment,M64(AS)-6, U.^."Department
     of Commerce, Washington, D. C., 1967.

64.   U.  S.  Bureau of Census, Census of Business 1963,
     Vol.  1-7, U. S.  Department of Commerce, Washington,
     D.  C., 1966.
                            -  103  -

                                     U. S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE : 1969 O - 330-619

-------