VOLUME


                           ONE

                           •
                           i
                           •
                            -
                            i
                            i
                            -
                            .
THE ECONOMICS OF CLEAN WATER
                            -





                           ...
                           i
                           h

                           --

                           HI


-------
                                                           2792
                THE ECONOMICS  OF

                   CLEAN WATER
                     VOLUME  I


               Detailed Analysis
        U.  S. Department of  the Interior

Federal  Water Pollution Control  Administration

	March 1970	

   For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office
               Washington, D.C. 20402 - Price $1.50

-------
                          UNITED STATES
                DEPARTMENT OF THE INTERIOR
                     OFFICE OF THE SECRETARY
                        WASHINGTON, D.C. 20240

                                              APR   31970


Dear Mr.  President:

I am transmitting  to the Congress the third report on the national
requirements  and cost of water  pollution control as required under
Section 16 (a)  of the Federal Water  Pollution Control Act, as amended.

The decade of the 1970's,  a  decade which will address itself to improv-
ing the quality of man's environment, will see great strides toward
the effort to abate water  pollution.  The enclosed report entitled
"The Economics  of Clean Water"  represents our current estimates of the
investment levels  necessary  to  attain applicable water quality
standards.

This report,  along with the  two previously submitted, contributes to
closing the information gap  in  terms of the overall magnitude, geograph-
ical, and financial dimensions, all  of which are essential to the
development of national policies and programs directed toward achieving
water quality standards in an efficient and effective manner.

The alternatives analyzed  in the course of this study, especially
those aspects contained in Volume I, presented valuable background
for development of proposals on aid  to municipal treatment works
presented to the Congress  in the President's Environmental Message
and subsequent  legislation.

There are four parts to this year's  report.  The first is a summary of
major findings  and conclusions  of the analysis.  The second, Volume I,
contains the details of the  analysis.  The third, Volume II, is a
profile of animal  wastes.  The  fourth and last section, Volume III,
is an industrial profile of  the inorganic chemicals industry.

                                    Sincerely yours,
                                     Secretary  6f  the Interior
Hon. Spiro Agnew
President of the Senate
Washington, D. C.  20510

Enclosure

-------
                          UNITED STATES

                DEPARTMENT OF  THE INTERIOR

                     OFFICE OF THE SECRETARY
                        WASHINGTON, D.C. 20240
                                               APR  31970
Dear Mr.  Speaker:

I am transmitting  to the Congress  the  third report on the national
requirements and cost of water pollution  control as required under
Section 16 (a)  of  the Federal  Water  Pollution Control Act, as amended.

The decade of the  1970's, a decade which  will address itself to improv-
ing the quality of man's environment,  will see great strides toward
the effort to abate water pollution.   The enclosed report entitled
"The Economics  of  Clean Water" represents our current estimates of the
investment levels  necessary to attain  applicable water quality
standards.

This report, along with the two previously submitted, contributes to
closing the information gap in terms of the overall magnitude, geograoh-
ical, and financial dimensions, all  of which are essential to the
development of national policies and programs directed toward achieving
water quality standards in an  efficient and effective manner.

The alternatives analyzed in the course of this study, especially
those aspects contained in Volume I, presented valuable background
for development of proposals on aid  to municipal treatment works
presented to the Congress in the President's Environmental Message
and subsequent legislation.

There are four parts to this year's  report.  The first is a summary of
major findings and conclusions of the  analysis.  The second, Volume I,
contains the details of the analysis.   The third,  Volume  II, is a
profile of animal  wastes.  The fourth  and last section, Volume III,
is an industrial profile of the inorganic chemicals  industry.
                                     Sincerely yours,
                                     Secretary of the Interior
Hon. John W. McCormack
Speaker of the House of
   Representatives
Washington, D. C.  20515

Enclosure

-------
                               CONTENTS

Introduction 	    1
Investment Trends 	    3
Development of Investment Needs 	   25
Federal Cost Sharing 	   67
Priority Systems 	  107
Public Treatment of Industrial  Wastes 	  121
Regional Waste-Handling Systems 	  143
Appendix—The Facilities Evaluation Model  	  161

                            LIST OF FIGURES

1.  States Classified According to Recent
      Investment Behavior 	    8
2.  Regional Definitions for Analysis of Comparative Unit
      Investment for Incremental Waste-Hand11 no
      Capabilities, 1962-1968	1	   41
3.  Investment Intentions Compared to Derived Needs 	    61
4.  Growth of Public Waste-Handling Services 	    75
5.  Public Investment in Waste-Handling Services
      1952-1967	    77
6.  Relative Domestic and Industrial Loading Public
      Waste Treatment Plants 	   128
7.  Application of Economies of Scale Through Consolidation
      of Waste Sources Producing 10 million gallons per
      day of sewage 	   133
                                  vii

-------
 8.   Unit Investment by Size of Place for Incremental
       Waste-Handling Capabilities, 1962-68 	   154

 9.   Generalized Ranking of Unit Cost and Removal  Efficiencies
       of Conventional Waste Treatment Processes 	   158
                             LIST OF TABLES
 1.   Comparative Investment Outlays for Waste-Handling
       Purposes, 1967 & 1968	     3

 2.   Estimated Annual Public Investment for Waste Treatment
       Plants and Ancillary Works, by State 	     5

 3.   Current Dollar Investment by States 1952-1968 	     6

 4.   Comparative Categorization of States by Recent
       Investment Behavior 	    10

 5.   Declining Investment States:  Relative Condition
       and Past Performance 	 	    13

 6.   Per-capita Investment Associated with Attainment of
       Water Quality Standards 1952-1969 	    15

 7.   Industrial Pollution Control Investments as Reported
       by McGraw H111 	    18

 8.   Summary of Data Reported for the Petroleum Industries
       by the American Petroleum Institute 	    19

 9.   Summary of Data Reported for the Chemicals Industrv
       by the Manufacturing Chemists Association 	    21

10.   Projected Cumulative Inorganic Chemical Industry Canital
       Costs and Annual Operating Costs for Waste Treatment	    23

11.   Evaluation of Capital in Place and of Defined Needs 1969	  27

12.   Normative Assessment of Annual Capital Needs Generated
       1n 1962 and 1968 	  29
                                   viii

-------
13.  Computed Values Associated with  Various  Categories of
       Investment Needs ........................................   30
14.  Increase 1n State Government—Defined Waste  Treatment
       Needs Overtime ..........................................   32
15.  Frequency of Major Plant Revisions  ........................   34
16.  Escalation of the Cost of a $1,000,000 Waste
       Treatment Plant, 1950-1969 ..............................   37
17.  Constant Dollar Investment Per Unit of Capacity,
       Activated Sludge Plant, 1961-63 and 1967-69 .............   39
18.  Normal Plant^ize Related to Relative Regional
       Unit Cost r ..............................................   44
19.  Wage Rates Related to Comparative Unit Costs ..............   46
20.  Major Components of Construction Cost .....................   47
21.  Relative Urbanization Related to Unit
       Waste-Handling  Investments ..............................    48
22.  Relative Construction Costs of an Activated
       Sludge Plant  ............................................    49
23.  Investment and  Demand, Northeastern States  ................    50
24.  Adjusted Investment Needs, Eight Northeastern States ......    51
25A. Five  Year  Backlog Elimination Schedule, Water
       Quality  Standards-Related Public  Investments .............    53
25B. Stretchout Schedule, Water Quality  Standards-Related
       Public Investments  .......................... •» ..........    54
 25C.  Deficiency  Schedule, Water Quality Standards-Related
        Pul     Investe         ....... , ............................   54
 26.   Summary of  Waste  Treatment Facilities by Year  Plant
        Underwent Major Revision (or Began)  .....................   56
                                    ix

-------
27.  Comparison of State Intentions and Derived Value
       of Needs .................................................  59
28.  Water Quality Standards-Related Manufacturers'
       Investment for Waste Treatment
       (Values in Millions of Current Dollars)  ..................  63
29.  Estimates of State and Local  Governments'  Needs
       for Federal Financial Support  ............................  70
30.  Relation of Federal Assistance to Total  Estimated
       Public Waste-Handling Expenditure  ........................  72
31.  Dollars of Total  Investment per  Dollars  of Federal
       Construction  Grants  ......................................  79
32.  Federal, State  and Local  Share of Financing  the Cost of
       Water Pollution  Control  Facilites  in New England  .........  »i
 33.   Per Capita Expenditures of State and Local  Governments
        for Sewerage Services ....................................   83
 34.   State and Local Governments'  Annual Expenditures  for
        Needed Public Water Pollution Control  Facilities  .........   85
 35.   Per Capita Expenditures of State and Local  Governments
        Fiscal Year 1968 .........................................   87
 36.   Per Capita Personal Income .................................   89
 37.   General Revenue of State and Local Governments
        Fiscal Year 1968 .........................................   91
 38.   Relationship of State and Local Governments' Annual
        Expenditures for Needed Water Pollution Control
        Facilities to Total General Revenue and Property
        Tax Capabilities .........................................   92
 39.   Moody's Rating of New England States and Selected
        Communities (December 1969) ..............................   95
 40.   Effect on Property Tax on a $20,000 Home 1n Financing
        Waste Treatment Facilities ...............................   98

-------
41.  Priority System Criteria 	   108

42.  Numerical Rank of Criteria by General  Categories 	   109

43.  Distribution of FWPCA Grants by Size of Comunity
       as of January 31, 1969 	   110

44.  Metropolitan and Non-Metropolitan Distribution of
       FWPCA Construction Grants, 1956-1968 	   Ill

45.  National Summary - Elapsed Time (mos.) Between Grant
       Offer and Construction Start 	   114

46.  National Summary of FWPCA Grants Approved and Still
       Pending as of 12/31/68	   115

47.  Unused Allotments by Fiscal Year	   118

48.  Pattern of Waste Discharges to Public Sewers by
       Manufacturing Plants Using 20 Million Gallons
       or More in 1964 	   123

49.  Distribution of Industrial Loadings to a Sample Group
       of Municipal Sewage Treatment Plants 	   125

50.  Relative Domestic and Industrial Loading of Municipal
       Waste Treatment Plants in 1968	   127

51.  Generalized Cost to Size Relationships of Basic
       Waste Treatment Processes  	   132

52.  Relative Prevalence of  Indus try—Provided and Publicly
       Provided Waste Treatment by Major Manufacturing
       Sectors, 1963  	   136

53.  Distribution of Waste Treatment Processes by
       Size  of Plant  	  157
                                   XI

-------
                             INTRODUCTION

    This is the third in a series of reports to the Congress  on the
subject of the cost of treating liquid wastes that the Secretary of
the Interior is charged to deliver annually, under the terms  of the
Federal Water Pollution Control Act.

    The first report in the series attempted to draw together and
evaluate in gross fashion all available information on water-borne
waste sources, treatment technology, and control deficiencies.  The
second report examined the processes of providing physical  caoital for
waste treatment—the interaction of funds over time under the influ-
ence of develooing technology, shifting regulatory requirements,
rising demand, and normal replacement conditions.

    This report combines the concept of investment processes  developed
in the second report with the generally held concept of an  investment
gap that was evaluated in the first report.  Its product is the
definition of a rate of investment that will close the gap  for munici-
pal and industrial waste treatment within a five year period, given
the continued pertinence of today's regulatory and technological
conditions.  Detailed studies of the pollutional impact of  the
inorganic chemicals industry and of concentrated animal populations
are submitted as separate sub-reports.

    The report considers several issues germane to the policy decisions
required with the expiration of current municipal grants legislation.
The alternatives and conclusions reached in this report are intended
to be illustrative and suggestive, not statements of policy.   Economic
analysis can provide insights into the consequences of alternative
actions, but the political process must in the final analysis mold
the necessary decisions within the context of total national  interests
and values.

    A number of subsidiary issues are considered, including the
influence of industrial waste discharges on public investment outlays,
the influence of location on unit investment, the status of broadly
integrated regional waste handling systems, the incidence of recapi-
talization, the influence of price levels on investment, and  patterns
of change in the real  cost (i.e., costs adjusted for price  levels
changes) of waste treatment facilities.  Consideration of these and
other sub-questions was consistently pointed to their relationship to
the problem of deriving a normative annual level of investment, one
aporopriate to five year attainment of an investment equilibrium in
the public waste treatment sector; and the force of Federal assist-
ance programs on investments is a minor theme that pervades the
report.

-------
                         INVESTMENT TRENDS
                    Recent Levels of Spending

     Total  Investment for liquid vraste handlinq facilities  was  little
changed in  196" from its 1967 level, due to pronounced declines  in
indicated industrial waste treatment investments and in the rate of
installation of sewers.
     Public investments amounted to 51,111.8 million, a more than
million increase over the previous year and a new high for the purpose.
That increase was concentrated in areas relating to vaste treatment--
public investments for collecting sewers were about 544 million lower
than in 1967, while spending for waste treatment, transmission, and
discharge facilities rose about 5102 million over the level of 1967.
Inflation, which exerted its pressures with increasing effect through
the course of the year, ate un most of the increase in oublic outlays.
Over 530 million of the $50 million increment in year to year public
spending is calculated to have been the consequence of higher prices.

                                Table 1

                    Comparative Investment Outlays for
                   '•faste-Handlinn Purposes , 1°67 £ 1968
Investment Category             Investment (millions of current dollars)

                                         1967               1968

New Waste Treatment Plants                14°                IPO
Expansion, Upgrading, Replacement         213                189
Interceptors & Outfalls                   138                M4
Collecting Sewers                         606                550
Industrial Waste Treatment                564                5?9

Total Capital Outlay                    1,7?0              1,73?

     Although information for investment in 1?*? is not fully avail-
able, preliminary indications are that it maintained its upward course.
Projections that were made in the first quarter of industrial outlays
indicated that over $700 pillion would be spent for waste-handling

-------
facilities in 1969.  (The value must be nresumed to be highly suspect,
in view of the wide divergence between projected and actual  investment
in 1968, when first quarter orojections derived from industrial  sources
suggested outlays approaching ^?W million for a year in which less
than $600 million was actually invested.)  One may infer, too, that
expenditures for installation of sanitary sewers were little, if any,
greater than in 196P>.  There is a nronounced secular downtrend in in-
vestments for oublic sewers; and the steep decline in new housing
starts experienced during the year suggests another drop in  the level
of Drivately funded sewer installation, which is directly related to
subdivision development.  But the segment of the market made us of
investments for waste treatment plants and ancillary works unquestion-
ably moved to a significantly higher level.  The assessment  is based
on projects receiving Federal construction grants that were  actually
started through the first ten ninths of 19F9.  The value of  those
projects—about $740 million—is consistent with an 'sRPO million full
year investment.  Table ?, that contrasts estimated 196° investments
for waste treatment plants and ancillary v.'orks with those of other
recent years, nay be distorted with resoect to tHe Interstate distrib-
ution of investment for 1%9, in that it assumes a constant  relationship
between ten month and twelve month investment for every State, but
the total may be presumed to be approximately accurate.

     Because of the acceleration of inflationary forces that vent on
through l°fi°, a very significant nortion of the year to.year increase
in investment was dissinated in price increases.  Assuming a constant
exertion of inflationary effects through the year, $47 mil lien of the
$12?* million rise in spending was accounted for by higher factor costs.

                    Influences on Public Investment

     New influences on the course of public waste handling investment
whose shape began to be discernible in 1967 and 196? took on sharper
outlines in 1^6°.  The prime influence on the level of spending since
the Korean war has been the amount of federal financing assistance that
has been made available to local governments.  When Federal  grants in
aid were initiated in 19S6, the pace of public investment accelerated
noticeably.  And as the amount of Federal assistance climbed in succes-
sive steps from ?50 million a year to $2^9 million a year, total
spending kept pace, in terms of direction and amount if not  of pro-
portion.  (See Table 3 for a State by State comparison of exnenditure
levels at oeriods marked by successive increases in the rate of Federal
financial assistance.)

     In recent years, however, the imoact of the amount of Federal subsi-
dies has been modified by other forces.  The maturity of the national
investment program has resulted in a sharply altered configuration
of capital needs.  State financial assistance to local communities
has complemented and redirected the force of Federal assistance.

-------
Alabama
Alaska
Arizona
Arkansas
California
Colorado
Connecticut
Delaware
District of Columbia
Florida
Georgia
Hawai i
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
lovia
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Maine
Maryland
Massachusetts
 Michigan
 Minnesota
 Mississippi
 Missouri
 Montana
 Nebraska
 Nevada
 New Hampshire
 New Jersey
 New Mexico
 New York
 North Carolina
 North Dakota
 Ohio
 Oklahoma
 Oregon
 Pennsylvania
 Rhode Island
  South Carolina
 South Dakota
 Tennessee
 Texas
 Utah
 Vermont
 Virginia
 Washington
 West Virginia
 Wisconsin
  Wyomi ng
  Puerto Rico

        Totals

      Millions of dollars
                                             TABLE 2
                                Estimated  Annual  Public Investment*
                                  for  Waste  Treatment Plants and
                                   Ancillary Works, by State
Average,
1962-66

  6.6
  0.3
  5.8
  6.4
 34.0
  7.4
  8.2
  2.2
  6.8
 10.6
  8.7
  5.5
  0.9
 30.9
 16.8
  7.3
  5.3
  7,0
 11.2
  3.3
  7.7
  12.4
  21.1
  10.4
  4.3
  21.1
   1.3
   4.8
   3.5
   3.1
  15.9
   3.4
  40.6
  14.8
   0.8
  23.5
   4.0
   5.5
  23.8
   2.8
   5.2
   1.5
  10.5
  17.5
   2.8
   3.4
   10
   20
    6
   18
    0
    1.8

  508.9
                                            1967
1968
12.6
0.1
5.4
10.7
43.0
3.0
17.7
_
13.6
9.4
13.2
4.4
1.3
45.3
24.4
8.2
5.2
4.0
7.6
1.4
20.2
6.7
7.6
8.6
2.7
15.2
0.5
4.5
3.4
2.0
30.0
4.0
33.3
18.7
0.8
26.1
6.5
3.2
42.6
1.0
4.6
2.9
5.1
14.9
1.9
1.8
20.9
3.8
1.2
13.4
3.8
542.4
4.3
4.0
2.9
3.2
34.9
4.6
7.9
1.0
3.2
16.8
4.5
-
0.7
33.5
27.1
13.1
11.1
4.4
4.5
5,7
17.3
13.4
30.4
13.3
2.7
26.5
1.3
2.0
0.4
6.0
10.5
0.4
115.0
10.8
0.3
35.1
5.5
3.3
65.3
1.2
10.5
0.2
19.9
17.1
0.1
2.4
10.4
20.9
3.0
17.1
-
652.1
1969 est.
              18.5
               0.2
               5.9
              10
              41
              10
              71
               1.4
               G.4
                 .6
                 .7
                 .5
                 .9
                 .2
                 .3
  29.
  22.
   0.
   1.
  33.
  10.
  H.6
   4.5
  10.9
  11.0
  10.0
  31.0
  28.1
    5.7
  13.3
    2.4
   12.8
    1.3
    3,0
                 .2
                 .9
                 .2
    0,
    1
   40,
    3.5
   97.0
   17.3
    0.4
   41.9
   14.6
    7.6
   90.2
    1.9
   26.0
    1.8
   13.6
   38.2
    1.2
    3.9
   25.0
     4.6
     4.0
   20.7
     0.8
     6.5

   880.8
1967-69 flyge
1962-66 Avg

       179%
       478%
        82%
       127%
       im
        82%
       395%
        36%
       114%
       17555
       155%
        30%
       144%
       121%
       123%
       164%
       131%
        92%
        69%
       7732
       297%
       130%
        69%
        79%
        66%
        38%
       106%
                                  77%
                                 201%
                                 105%
                                  63%
                                 146%
                                 222%
                                  85%
                                 277%
                                  49%
                                 263%
                                 109%
                                 138%
                                 134%
                                  38*
                                  79%
                                 175%
                                  48%
                                  44%
                                  94%
                                 133%
                                  136%

-------
                                          TABLE 3
                        Current  Dollar  Investment by States 1952-1968
                                (Millions of  Current Dollars)
Alabama
Alaska
Arizona
Arkansas
California
Colorado
Connecticut
Delaware
District of  Columbia
Florida
Georgia
Hawaii
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Maine
Maryland
Massachusetts
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
New Hampshire
New Jersey
New Mexico
New York
North Carolina
 North Dakota
Ohio
Oklahoma
Oregon
Pennsylvania
 Rhode Island
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Utah
Vermont
Virginia
Washington
West Virginia
Wisconsin
Wyoming
Puerto Rico

        Totals
1952-1955

   11.4

    1.1
    2.8
   46.8
    3.6
    4.6
    4.9
    2.0
   39,2
    6.3
    0.
    33.
    59.
    10.2
    15.1
    12.9
     4.2
     0.7
     6.7
      .3
      .2
      .5
14
34
16
 1.7
 8.6
 0.8
 1.4
 2.5
 0.9
81.1
 3.0
66.7
12.2
 1.0
61.5
 9.5
10.5
51.1
 5.5
 3.4
 1
24.
24.1
 4.9
 0.7
17.9
 6.6
 8.2
12.4
 0.6
  753.6
      .7
      .3
                .2
                .4
                .7
                .5
1956-1961

   31.9
    2.2
   12.8
   16.0
  213.9
   17.3
   19.8
    5.0
   33.2
   43.
   32.
    5.8
    8.6
  127.
   97.
   33.0
   35.3
   38.7
   25.0
    3.8
   28.
   31
   83.
   36.
   IV
   26.
    8.
   26.0
    6.0
    4.6
   75.6
   12.2
  171.0
   51.5
    8.8
  166.0
   19.7
   20.1
  208.4
    7.3
    9.9
    5.3
   36.0
   60.8
   17.9
    6.2
   37.0
   37.5
   32.7
   52.0
    6.5
    0.5

  2107.8

     6
.4
.6
.4
.3
.1
.2
.2
                                                       1962-1966
           32.8
            1.7
           29,
           32.1
          170.1
           36
           41
           10.8
           33.9
           53.0
                              1
                              .9
                              .1
           43.
           27.
            4.7
          154.6
           84.
           36.
           26.
   .5
   .5
   .2
   .4
   .6
                            35.0
 55.9
 16.6
 38.7
 62.0
105.6
 52.
 21
105.6
  6.4
 24.
 17.
 15.
 79.
.2
.5
                               17.0
           203.2
            74.2
             4.1
           117.5
            20.0
            27.6
           119.2
            13.8
            25.8
             7.3
            52.
            87.
            14.
   .3
   .6
   .2
                                17.0
                                  .3
                                  .5
            53.
           102.
            30.8
            90.9
             1.2
             9.3

          2544.3
           1967-1968

              16.9
               4.1
               8.3
              13.9
              77.9
               7.
              25.
               0.
             .6
             .6
             .9
                                         16.8
             .2
             .7
26.
17.
 4.4
 2.0
78.8
             .2
             .3
             .3
51
21
16
 8.4
12.1
 7.1
37.5
20.1
           38.0
 21
  5.
 41
  1
  6.
  3.8
  8.0
 40.5
  4.4
148.3
 29.5
  1.1
.9
.4
.7
.8
.5
                                               .2
                                               .0
           61
           12.
             6.5
           107.9
             2.2
           15.1
             3.1
           25.0
           32.0
             2.0
             4.2
           31
           24.
             4.2
           30.5
                 .3
                 .7
                                           3.8

                                        1192.0
                      Total  for
                       Period

                         93.0
                          8.0
                         51.3
                         64.8
508
 65
 91
 21
 85
161
 99
 37
                 7
                 ,4
                 .1
                 ,6
                 ,9
                 .6
                 .9
                 .7
                                                           16.0
394.
292.
100,
  93.
                                       95.0
                                                       97
                                                       28
                                                      111
                        128.0
                .2
                .9
                .7
                .1
 261
 126.
  39.
 182.
  17.2
  58.0
  30.0
  29.0
 276.9
  36.
 589.
 167.4
  15.0
 406.
  61
  64.
 486.
                               .6
                               .2
                               .2
                               .2
                               .7
                               .6
              28.8
              54.2
              17.4
             137.6
             204.5
              39.0
                 .1
                 .5
                 .3
  28.
 139.
 171,
  75.9
 185.8
   8.3
  13.6

6597.7

-------
Public awareness of water quality problems has developed a sense of
urgency and a heightening of the investment effort in some cases.  Out
of the inter-action of assistance programs, needs patterns, and local
preference, an alteration of the investment structure has emerged.
Where almost every State in the past moved its investment levels
uniformly upward from period to period (subject to year to year
lumpiness imparted by intermittent new starts on extremely large
projects), divergent trends have become evident over the last three
years.  Some States continue to increase the amount of their investment-
some at fairly constant, some at accelerating rates—others appear
to have reached at least an interim equilibrium level with respect
to public investments for water pollution control, and still a third
group aopears to be deemphasizing  public investment for protection of
the aquatic environment.

     There is a rough correspondence between location and investment
behavior.  If one considers the forty-eight contiguous States and the
District of Columbia (Alaska, Hawaii, and Puerto Rico are special
cases, quite different from the rest of the nation in the condition of
their water pollution control programs), he finds that thirteen of the
twenty-two States west of the Mississippi have maintained stable or
declining investment levels over the last three years, and only two of
the western States fall into a category composed of States whose
spending has increased fifty percent or more.  (cf. Figure 1.)
Conversely, seventeen of the twenty-seven eastern States have increased
their capital outlays for waste treatment facilities; and the class
of States with the largest proportional increases are concentrated in
the extreme northeast and deep south.  (Four northeastern States--
Connecticut, New Jersey, New York, and Pennsylvania—account for almost
seventy percent of the increase in average annual investments for the
period 1967-69 as compared to 1962-66.)

     That geographic pattern fits generally, though not invariably,
the pattern of distribution of v/aste treatment amona the individual
States.  That is to say, the more complete a State's waste treatment
services, the greater the probability that it is now reducing invest-
ment, relative to other States.  The relationship is comforting, in
that it suggests that in some crude fashion—with, unfortunately, gaps
and overlays—investment has a configuration that matches the occur-
rence of needs, as well as in the implication that at. some point of
attainment to be reached in the future, every State will be  able to
relax the comparative intensity of its investment effort.

     There are also disturbing elements in the distribution  of  invest-
ment intensity.  On the one hand there are the cases of apparent
laxness, States that show a pronounced relative deficiency  in waste
treatment services with no corresoonding  increase in investment  effort.
On the other hand, there are indications  of  pronounced  relative  inef-
ficiency, in that the level of a State's  nast effort may be  related

-------

          STATES CLASSIFIED'ACCORDING
             TO RECENT INVESTMENT
                    BEHAVIOR
                                                             ua
                                                             (D
STATES INCREASING INVESTMENT 50% OR MORE
STATES INCREASING INVESTMENT 11-49%
STATES WITH STABLE INVESTMENTS
STATES WITH INVESTMENTS DECLINING 11-25%
STATES WITH INVESTMENTS DECLINING 25% OR MORE

-------
only slightly to its current status.  Harked increases in expenditures
have been initiated in cases where per-caoita spending was equal  to or
greater than that of States whose relative needs are slighter and whose
spending has been controlled or reduced in recent years.

     The broad outlines of the developing investment structure come
into sharper focus if States are categorized according to their
recent investment behavior.  Table 4 presents such a classification,
with all values reduced to relative terms—percentages or per-caoita
values—to provide an element of comparability.  It should be stressed
that what is true of a class of States, as they are distinguished in
the table, is not necessarily true of every State within the class.
The only distinction recognized in setting up the groupings was invest-
ment behavior, and distinct differences may be found amonn units  whose
investment behavior is similar.  Thus in the group of States with
stable investment, Mew Hampshire, with only 4.5% of the sewered
population of the grouping, includes 50.3% of its population with
untreated wastes, 7.1% of its peculation V'/ith wastes receiving only
primary treatment, and 27% of the amount of its investment requirements.
Similarly, in the group of States with modestly declining investments,
the State of Vermont has only 2.9% of the group's population, but
contains 9.7% of its population without waste treatment, 8.5% of  its
population with only primary treatment, and 15.7%  of the value of
the group's investment requirements.  Obviously, each group would
compare even more favorably with the other three groups if the atypical
component were removed.  The intra-classification  discrepancy is
acute in the case of the grouping of states whose investments in  the
last three years have sunk below 75% of the rate of the previous  five
years.  That discrepancy is discussed below.

     1)  That group of States in which investments were being acceler-
ated most vigorously during the last three years--50% or more over the
average annual level of the five years before—includes more than a
third of the sewered ponulation of the United States.  Those States'
emphasis on waste-handling investment will, then, have a strong influence
on the level of total investment.

     The sharp acceleration of investment by these particular States
would appear to be desirable, in that the qrouo contains a relatively
large proportion of the waste treatment needs of the nation.  No matter
how needs are viewed in comparison with the oonulation base—propor-
tionate discharge of raw sewage, prooortion of sewered population vn'th
only primary waste treatment, proportion of evaluated investment
needs--!t would aooear that these States, as a group, are behind the
rest of the nation and should be increasing their share of national
investment.  That very general conclusion is supported by a review
of comparative investments:  as a group, they have invested less,
on a per-capita basis, over most of the last fifteen years than most
other States.

-------
                                                                          TABLE  4
                                                            Comparative  Categorization of States
                                                                by  Recent  Investment Behavior
                                                                       Percent  of  national Total
Sewered Sewered Pop. Sewered Pop.
Population w/o Treatment w/PMtnary Trtmt.
States with major Increases (ISOX or more of
1962-66 average) 1n Investment In 1967-69:
Alabama, Alaska, (Connecticut), Florida,
Georgia. Iowa, (Maine). (Maryland). (New
Jersey). (New YoHTTOklaHoma. (Pennsylvania) .
South Carolina, Virginia, Puerto mco 35.6 42.1 38.0
States with Increases (111-149% of 1962-66
average) 1n Investment In 1967-69:
Arkansas, California. District of Columbia,
Idaho, Illinois, (Indiana), Kansas,
(Massachusetts), Minnesota, Ohio, Tennessee,
Texas. Wyoming "" 42.6 30.2 38.1
States with substantially unchanged (90-110%
Of 1962-66 average) 'Investment In 1967-69:
Kentucky, New Hampshire. North Carolina,
south Dakota, Wisconsin 5.1 3.3 3.3
States with declining (75-89S of 1962-66
average) Investment 1n 1967-69:
Arizona, Colorado, Missouri, Montana,
(New Mexico), (Oregon"}, (Vermont) 5.3 1.8 3.9
States with sharply declining (74% or less
than 1962-66 average) Investment 1n 1967-69:
(Delaware), Hawaii, Louisiana, (Michigan),
Mississippi, Nebraska, Nevada, North Dakota,
(Rhode Island), UfaTi, (Washington),
West Virginia 12.6 20.0 17.5
United States Totals 100.0 100.0 100.0
Current
Investment Investment
1952-66 1967-69 Requirements
32.9 48.9 40.2
39.4 33.9 32.0
7.7 6.4 6.7
6.9 5.8 7.0
14.3 6.8 14.1
100.0 100.0 100.0
                                                                                                                       Average" Annual Per-Caplta InvesTmenT*
                                                                                                                        1952-55  1956-61  1962-66  1967-69
                                                                                                                         (1.95)
                                                                                                                          1.60
                                                                                                                          (1.64)
                                                                                                                          1.34
                                                                                                                          (1.77)
                                                                                                                          1.45
                                                                                                                          (1.21)
                                                                                                                          0.99
                                                                                                                          (1.34)
                                                                                                                           1.10

                                                                                                                          (1.67)
                                                                                                                           1.37
(2.40)
 2.42
(2.57)
 2.60
(3.63)
 3.67
(2.37)
 2.39
(2,56)
 2.59

(2.54)
 2.56
(2.88)
 3.20
(2.85)
 3.16
(5.82)
 6.46
(6.02)
 6.68
(4.50)
 5.00

(3.33)
 3.70
(5.37)
 6.98
(3.11)
 4.04
(4.91)
 6.38
(4.29)
 5.58
(2.12)
 2.76

(3.91)
 5.08
* Per-caplta Investment based on 1968 sewered population,  Constant (1957-59)  Dollars  1n  Parentheses

Note: States which provide financial  assistance are underlined and States  with  funded assistance  programs  are  indicated  by  parantheses.

-------
     That investment deficiency nay have been in part a result of
Federal policy.  These are in many instances the high population, big
city states that, because of grant limitations, received effectively
less per-capita Federal assistance under the terms o* the Federal
V/ater Pollution Control Act as it VMS structured betvreen 1956 and 1966.
Though per-capita investment in these States shoved a response to the
availability of Federal grants after 1°56, tHe amounts of the increases
in per-capita expenditures were well below that of other qroups of
states before 1967.   Those States now demonstrating the greatest
increase in investment are, however, the sane group that provided the
highest per-capita investment before Federal construction assistance
programs were initiated.  In a sense, the major 1966 amendments of the
Federal Water Pollution Control Act tended to redress maldistribution
of Federally supplied resources and to allow these States to step up
their investments sufficiently to begin to close gaps that had opened
betv/een them and others.

     But increased amounts of Federal assistance and less discriminatory
Federal allocation procedures have probably been of lesser moment in
levering investments of at least some States within this group upward
than has the initiation of State financial assistance for construction
of waste treatment facilities,  fost of these States provide such
assistance, and have fully funded their assistance programs.  In at
least two instances—New York and "aryland—State capital inputs over
the last three years have matched or exceeded the amount of Federal
assistance.

     ?.}  Another group of States, one that contains over 40" of the
Nation's sewered population, is also undergoing a marked expansion of
capital emplacement  rates.  Almost four out of five Americans, then,
live in States that  are still  in the process of increasing public
expenditures for water nollution control.

     The class of States in which investment is rising at rates that
approximate rather than exceed the degree of increase exoerienced in
the decade and a half before 1967 tend to have achieved far more
effective control  of wastes than have the States that are undertaking
a more pronounced exoansion of investment.  The group of States under
consideration have invested less, on a total and on a per-capita basis,
than the class of States whose annual expenditures are registering
a more marked increase, yet they display lower than proportional shares
of population without waste treatment or only primary treatment; and
evaluation of their  waste treatment deficiencies shows them to be less
than proportional  to population.

     Relatively efficient use of capital, then, distinguishes them, in
that their per-capita expenditures have been consistently lower than
those in the other investment categories, while their indicated
deficiencies in level of service contrast favorably with the others.  In
spite of those efficiencies, it has proved necessary for them to
                                  11

-------
increase their level of investment continuously.  These are, as a
group, States whose population growth is distinctly above the national
average.  They are also States that have consistently provided an above
average level of waste treatment services.  It would appear that
pressures of growth, recapitalization, and upgrading will continue to
operate on these States, and that their expenditures may continue to
rise—perhaps ultimately attaining a per-capita level somewhat closer
to the national average.

     It is notable in this regard that the group of States character-
ized by moderately rising investment has in the past shared, at least
in some cases, the disadvantaged position with respect to Federal
financial assistance of the*States whose investments have been rising
most rapidly; and that—though some of the States involved provide
financial assistance to communities—their expenditures have generally
followed the regulator of investment intensity orovided by Federal
grants.

     3)  Federal grants would seem to have served as the principal
regulator in the case of the small number of States who have, on the
basis of investments during the last eight years, reached some sort
of equilibrium position for waste treatment investments.

     They are States that have, as a grouo, achieved a high level
of control of public wastes.  They are not, it would appear,
extremely efficient as compared to others.  Though they have achieved
an interim equilibrium level of per-capita investment, it is at a
rate that has been consistently higher than that of other groups of
States until very recently.

     Low population, non-metropolitan States, they have been so
structured as to achieve maximum per-capita assistance from Federal
construction grants.  With Federal assistance at $100 million a year,
these States achieved a level of per-capita spending close to twice
that of more heavily populated States, and the rise in amount of Federal
grant allotments to $200 million a year induced no investment response
on their part.

     4)  The group of States whose investments ar» declining moderately
but perceptibly is in many respects much like the group whose invest-
ments are stable.  These, too, are States with a relatively small
metropolitan population component who were able to materially accel-
erate their investment under federal assistance totalling $100 million
a year.  Per-capita capital application in this group of States, too,
has been similar to that of States with stable investment—though their
investment is currently lower, it was somewhat higher in the previous
period; and over the eight year period 1°6?-F0, thp  tv;o  groups of States
mounted constant dollar per-capita investment efforts that were within
?." of one another in amount.  The parallel investment experience of
                                  12

-------
these two groups of States that have largely overcome their v/aste treat-
ment deficiencies is, perhans, indicative of v;hat the nation as a whole
can anticipate in terras of sustained investment needs.  If so, annual  in-
vestments of more than five 1957-59 dollars for each person receiving
sewer services may be sore sort of an underlying investment base for
a mature waste treatment sector.

     5)  States whose investments have declined steeply in the last
three years do not fall into a single pattern.   They are widely dis-
tributed with respect to location; they include both industrial and
agricultural economies; some include predominantly snail town and rural
populations, others are metropolitan in character.

     More significant with resnect to this discussion of investment
behavior is the relative prevalence of waste treatnent among the mem-
bers of the groun.  There are twelve States whose waste treatment
investments have been cut back sharply over the last three years.  Six
of these—Delaware, Nevada, North Dakota, Rhode Island, Utah, and
Washington—are much like the groups of States  with stable or moderate-
ly declining investments in terms of past performance.  The other six
                                  a high pronortion of untreated or
                                  low level of  investment in the past.
                                  States who are now increassing invest-
combine a drop in  investment with
inadequately treated wastes  and a
They are, in short,  much like the
ments most sharply,   (cf.  Table 5.)
                                TABLE 5

                Declining Investment States:   Relative
                    Condition and Past Performance
                                            I

                                     Delaware, Nevada,
                                     N. Dakota, Rhode
                                     Island, Utah,
                                     Washington
Percent of Nation's sewered population
Percent of Nation's sewered population
     without waste treatnent
Percent of Nation's sewered population
     with only orimary waste treatment
Percent of national investment: 1952-6?
                                1^67-69
Constant dollar per-capita investment:
     1952-69
                                         3.P

                                         1.0

                                         3.5
                                         5.n
                                         2.1

                                       $64.34
   II

Hawaii, La.,
Michigan,
Nebr., West
Virginia

  o n
  ,. » V,-

 19.0

 13.9
  9.3
  4.7

M8.76
                                  13

-------
     The behavior of the first group is expectable i> terms of their
situation and nicht have been predicted; the decline in their activity
comes after a period of intense investment, and occurs in situations
marked by a  high level of vaste control.  The second group is an_
anomaly.  Investments  in the past have been near or below the national
average on a per-c?pita basis; they contain an abnormally laroe proportion
of the nation's population without waste treatment or with only primary
treatment; and their investment needs--in  terms of physical facility
needs defined bv the States themselves—are disproportionately great.
Yet  in circumstances that  include thoso indications of likely to be
rising or at least  stable  outlays, and in  the face of a doubling of
the  level of Federal grant assistance, they have cut back on investments.

     One may assume, perhaps, that there are special local circumstances
in every case that  help to exolain the investment decline.  And it is
not  unreasonable to suppose that these particular States may simply
be demonstrating in extreme form the effects of high interest Crates and
constraints on the  supply  of money, and may in fact preview similar
investment declines in other areas as such financial constraints become
extensively operative. Another mechanism, too, nay be partially re-
sponsible for these States' declining investment.  Removal of the
dollar  limitations  on  Federal grants have  made them applicable to com-
munities of all  sizes, and where State financial assistance becomes
available to communities,  the major portion of the financial load is
removed  from their  shoulders.  I'nder those conditions, the amount of
Federal  and State grants would constitute  the principal limiting factor
in  determining level  of  investment.  Mo community could be expected to
begin  a  project  in  the absence of  a full share of Federal and State
assistance.  Thus the  potential  availability of assistance may«vhen
it  is  inadequate to conditions— serve to  reduce rather than  increase
the  level of local  effort.  Inadequate Federal allocations, unfunded
State  assistance programs, even  the possibility of the introduction
in  a State  legislature of  a  bill to provide assistance, can have  the
effect  of limiting  local  investments:  and  sue* mechanisms may well  be
operative  in the cases of  these  six States.   Arguing for  such  a
phenomenon  is  the fact that  those  States whose outlays are  increasing
most rapidly include  several  cases where State government  has agreed
to  pre-finance the  Federal share of local  projects, thus  eliminating
the  level of Federal  allocations as a  constraint on investment.

               Relative  Efficiency and Public  Investment

     The data on per-capita  investment  by  classes mcy offer  some
inconclusive but useful  insights into  the  relative  efficiency of  the
various  investment  groupings,  as well  as  into  the  level of investment
to  be  anticipated under  a  condition of comolete  treatment services.
                                   14

-------
     Table 6 'summarizes the constant dollar per-capita investment of
each of the classes of States for the period 1952 through 1969 and
contrasts that amount with the constant dollar value of current invest-
ment needs listed by each State,  (cf. Chapter Two:  Development of
Investment Needs for derivation.)  It may very reasonably be concluded
that the eighteen year investment plus the value of the investment
remaining to be made provides an accounting of the per-capita burden
associated with attainment of water quality standards at this time.

                                TABLE 6

                 Per-capita Investment Associated with
                 Attainment of Water Quality Standards,
                               1952-1969

                  (All  values in 1957-59 dollars)

Investment Status    Per-canita investment   Per-capita amount   TOTAL
                           since 1952        of remaining needs
Sharply Increasing           49.23                32.25         PI.48
Increasing                   45.56                20.98         66.54
Stable                       59.63                36.88        106.51
Declining                    62.03                37.10         00.13
Sharply Declining            49.5*                25.05         74.63
     The values obtained by the exercise are extremely surprising.  If
they are to be taken at face value, they suggest that there are extre-
mely wide variations in investment efficiency, that the least efficient
users of capital  have'achieved the highest level of control of their
wastes, and that the less capital  a State has provided in the past, the
smaller the burden waste treatment will mean to its citizens in the
future.

     Although there are knovrn to be wide variations in investment
efficiency (the point is discussed later in this report), the
implications to be drawn from the values presented in the table seem
to be distorted,  particularly when geography is taken into account.
Many of the States that are found in the investment groupings that
represent increasing investment, as well as several among the six
poorer performing States in the category of sharply decreasing invest-
ments, are located in the regions where canital efficiency has been
demonstrated to be low.  A more realistic analysis of the situation may
well be that there is a tendency for States whose deficiencies are
great to underestimate the extent, of these deficiencies.  Evaluation
of waste treatment deficiencies may depend to some degree on relative
accomplishment, so that States with effective and well advanced pol-
lution control programs may list as needed improvements situations that
                                  15

-------
less effective states would find quite satisfactory.  If this is in
fact the case, then those States who are now increasing their invest-
ments—not to mention those whose investments should be increasing
when they are in fact declining—may find the .job that they have set
out to acconplish considerably more expensive than is indicated by
their view of current conditions.

           Industrial Hater Pollution Control Expenditures

     In sharp contrast  to 1968, when the high degree of visibility
given to water pollution control by institution of water quality
standards caused a flurry of  industrial analyses, information with
regard to industrial pollution abatement expenditures was scarce in
1969.  The only available source of comprehensive data was the annual
McGraw Hill Survey of Business Plans for Plant and Equipment.  According
to the Survey, industrial investments for pollution control in 1%8
were well below first quarter projections.  And the planned investment
level for 1969, though  higher than actual 1968 expenditures, was
significantly lower than the  rate of spending initially projected for
1968, as shown in Table 7.

     The report may—though it is not certain—be reason for concern.
Of the total $776 million of  manufacturing investment, 50 to 55% may
be consigned to water pollution control, on the basis of past invest-
ment relationships.  That amount—$390 to $4?5 million—represents a
sharp drop in the level of industrial v/ater pollution control invest-
ment from the $500 to $600 million of 1967, during a year of record
capital spending.  Strong inflationary pressures during the year may
be thought to have reduced the effectiveness of the investment.  The
amount—even without adjustment for the greater than expected inflation
of construction costs that occurred—is well below the mean goal of
$502.6 million for industrial waste treatment investments in 1968 that
was established in the  first  renort of this series.

     Finally, the forty percent increase in investment planned for
1969 must be considered to be suspect, in view of the wide (49%)
difference between actual expenditures in 1968 and report plans.

   Unfortunately, the area of certainty is so small with respect
to industrial v/ater pollution control that is is impossible to
evaluate the real significance of the indicated drop in investment
during 1968.  Certainly, deviation from the targeted goal is not in
itself enough to cause  concern.  The range of target expenditure
levels—$328 million to $677  million—is so great as to indicate
that, in spite of the drop in spending, industry may still be making
acceptable progress toward the goal.  The gap between projected and
actual expenditures in  1968 may well be traceable to slow deliveries
and extended construction schedules, problems that plagued all types
of construction in the  super-heated capital spending atmosphere of
                                  16

-------
                                 TABLE 7
               Industrial Pollution Control Investments,
                      as Reported by "cGraw Hill
                        (Millions of Dollars)

INDUSTRY                        Projected    Actual    Planned
                                  1968        1968       1969

Iron * Steel                     $  144       $  123    $  184
Monferrous net?Is                   37           13        51
Electrical machinery               116           3«        A 7
Machinery                           41           5P        83
Autos, trucks ' Darts               66           29        4Q
Aerospace                            s           14        15
Other transp. equipment
  (RR Equipment., shins)             3           12        17
Fabricated metals ?- instruments     41           40        57
Stone, clay ? glass                 40           33        56
Other durables                      ?9           2°        93

TOTAL DURABLES                     585          3RP       652
ALL INDUSTRY                    SI ,B5R
Chemicals                          112          104       126
Paper ?< pulp                        91           91       1°*
Rubber                               6            6        11
Petroleum                          1^2          157       160
Food ?. beverages                    32           15        31
Textiles     "                      26           13        1°
Other nondurable                   40            ?        10
TOTAL NONDURABLES                  40Q          388

ALL MANUFACTURING                  °9^»          776     1,113
Mining                              83           4°        71
Electric 5 oas utilities           481          223       ?M
                                  17

-------
the last two years.  Nor  is  it unlikely  that a number of industrial
pollution control projects were revised  to  take advantage of public
waste handling facilities, a  practice that  anpears to be increasingly
prevalent.  (The practice could conceivably have reduced the level
of industrial investment  in  two ways:  1)   substitution of public
facilities for planned  treatment  plants  would cause a positive shift
of investment to the public  sector-,  2)  delays encountered in public
investment would cause  postponement  of industrial investments for
connection and transmission  facilities.)

     The lack of reliable information on industrial water pollution
control activities  might  be  considered to be intolerable, if the
nation  had not become quite  habituated to it.  The guessing process
has gone on for so  long that it  is  considered quite normal; and
every effort  to initiate  an  industrial waste inventory has been
frustrated without  noticeable public comment.

     In an effort to  reduce  the  area of  uncertainty, FWPCA has
contracted with the National  Industrial  Conference Board to survey a
substantial number  of manufacturing  firms during 1970 with respect to
their water nollution control practices  and expenditures.  It is  the
hope of the Federal Water Pollution  Control Administration that the
use of  a  private contractor  with  an  impeccable reputation for discre-
tion and  accuracy will  reduce management fears of disclosure—fears
based,  apparently,  on a desire to maintain  intearity of proprietary
kinds of  data as much as  on  the  possibility of the use of such data
for enforcement purposes  if  Federally collected—and assure the aqency
of reliable information of a breadth and ooint beyond anything
previously attained for the  industrial waste treatment activity.  Given
industrial cooperation  with  the  proposed survey, FVIPCA should be
able to report to the Congress in 1971 with authority beyond anything
previously attempted  in connection  with  industrial waste treatment.

                             Special  Studies

     In late  1968 and early  1969, the American Petroleum Institute and
the Manufacturing Chemists Association  published napers
on pollution  control  expenditures relating  to  broad surveys of their
memberships.  Those reports, interesting in themselves, are also  of
value for their corroborative properties.   In  general, they support
the findings  of the 1968  report  to  Congress on The Cost of Clean  Water,
as those findings relate  to  the  specific industrial sectors; and  the
investment rates indicated are of an order  to  magnitude that is compa-
tible with the estimates  of  capital  emplacement  rates presented in the
1969 report on The  Cost of Clean  '.-later  and^Its^^gjnonr[c Jmpact.

     The petroleum  industry  data  summarized in Table  8 is based on
responses to  questionnaires  submitted to 39 firms,  35 of whom respond-
ed.  The respondents are  credited with  97%  of  refinery throughput of


                                  18

-------
                                             TABLE 8
                     Summary of Data Reported for the Petroleum Industries
                             by The American Petroleum Institute*

                                                            Thousands of Dollars
     1966
     1967
     1968
     1°66
     1967
     1968
     1966
     1967
cpendl turps Total



Charges



tive ?,



Report
in the
79,016 I/
133, 728 I/
122,679 4/

45,7°7 2/
53,246 2/
56,^00 4/
Research Exnonditures
20, "03
23,842
26,200 4/
Manufacturing
18,138 I/
40,000 V


IP,, 33° 2/
21 ,030 £/


12,75" 3/
14,681 3/

on Air «'• Hater Conservation Expendi turns
United States, Cross ley
S-D Survey, Inc.
Production
57,968
70,318


25/23
30,103


6,833
7,757

of The Petrol
Transportation
786
1,017


1 ,41°
1,377


82
101

euro Industry
Marketi nq
2,124
2,393


616
736


1,229
1,303


, New York, August 1%8.
*Source:
I/ Includes ^l,4nl,nno in 1966 and ^,770,000 in 1967 at chemicals plants
2/ Includes ^3,375,000 in 1°66 and ";3,nn9,nno in 1°67 at chenicals plants
3/ Includes environmental research and testing that cuts across functional  lines.
V   Estimated

-------
the Industry, so results may be considered to Include substantially
all of the manufacturing segment of the United States petroleum
Industry.  Given the predominant integration of the industry, it may
be inferred that a majority of crude oil and gas production is also
represented.  The data  is  unsatisfying in some respects.  It fails to
provide an assessment of total value of capital in place, and it
provides no indication  of  the effectiveness of expenditures.

      It does provide some  very useful new insights into the total
industrial pollution abatement situation, however.  Surprisingly,
expenditures in  connection with petroleum extraction have exceeded
those in manufacturing  activities.  Another surprising relationship is
the  high ratio of research and administrative charges to operating
charges.   Even allowing for  public  relations motivated padding, it
would appear that hidden  costs of pollution control are significant
enough to  warrant considerable industrial interest.

      The Manufacturing  Chemists  Association data summarized in
Table 9 are  in  several  ways  more  useful  than that available for the
petroleum  industries.   In addition  to  information concerning recent
investment and operating  charges,  it  provides a comprehensive look
at total  investment, water use,  and investment efficiency that is
based on  987  plants operated by  129 firms that represent 90* of the
chemicals  production  capacity of the  nation.

      Interestingly,  the industry's  reduction of organic wastes—about
 57%—is almost  precisely the same as  the 593 calculated for the
 aggregate public waste treatment plant of the nation.  The report
also notes that  of  the industry's  total  surface water discharge,
 38% required  no  treatment, 45$ met  all  regulatory treatment require-
ments, and only 17?  involved some kind of waste  treatment deficiency.
 In this connection,  it should be noted that the  limited reduction of
 inorganic wastes—only 27%—does not take into account the effects
of neutralization,  a  widely used treatment technique that does not
 involve actual  materials reduction.

      A detailed report on waste  disposal in the   inorganic chemicals
 industry was  prepared for the FWPCA under contract  by Cyrus William
 Rice Co.  in cooperation with W.  Wesley Eckenfelder,  Jr., Resource
 Engineering,  Inc.,  and Datagraphics, Inc., (separately  printed as
 Volume III of this  report).   It presents a description  of the industry,
 and the costs  it would incur in  attaining various  levels of  pollution
 abatement over a five  year period through 1974.   The cost estimates
 have been based upon  published data, general  data derived from  inform-
ation in the  files  of the Contractors' on industrial  waste  treatment
methods and costs,  and specific data from 59 inorganic  chemical  plants,
 some of which  were  supplied by the Manufacturing Chemists  Association.

      The inorganic  chemical  industry was defined to include establish-
ments producing  alkalies and chlorine, industrial  gases, inorganic
                                    20

-------
                               TABLE 9
          Summary of  Data Reported for the Chemicals Industry
               by the Manufacturing Chemists Association

Water Use (Gallons/Day)
     Total                                        11,695,875,000
     Cooling water only                            9,301,262,^00

Water Discharged (Gallons/day)
     Total   "                                     11,192,385,000
     Through public sewers                           101,735,000

Inorganic Wastes (Pounds/Day)
     Total                                           20<5,088,noo
     Discharged to water                             146,911,WO
     Discharged to public savers                       2,34P,000

Organic Wastes (Pounds/Day)
     Total                                            11,481/100
     Discharged to water                               3,°43,000
     Discharged to nublic sewers                       1,005,000

Water Pollution Control Expenditures
     Capital investment through 1966             5   385,268,^00
     Onerating charges, 1966                     $    59,638,000
     Average Annual investment, 1962-66          $    28,128,000
     Average Annual investment projected,
              1967-71                            5    47,140,000

Source:   Toward A. Clean  Environment.  A 1967 Survey  of the Members
          of the Manufacturing Chemists Association.
                                   21

-------
pigments, paints and allied products, fertilisers (excluding ammonia
and urea), inorganic insecticides and herbicides, exnlosives, and other
major industrial inorganic chemicals.  The complex relationship which
exists between various products and industries, however, make it
extremely difficult to arbitrarily associate certain oroducts with one
category.  The overall output of the industry, since its products
are used for a wide variety of purposes well removed fror the final
consumer, depends unon the level of total economic activity rather
than the economic activity in any one segment of the economy.  Since
new mineral sources are discovered infrequently and usually involve
large development expenditures, wide fluctuations in the gap between
demand and readily available supply are quite common.

     Total production  in  the inorganic chemical industry is estimated
to be 3??.7 billion nounds in 1969 and is projected to be ^55.5 billion
rounds in 197*-.  While certain segments of the industry are growing
as raoidly as  l°°o per  year, the historical growth is 1.* to 2.r times
that of  the gross national product.  The overall irice index of in-
organic  chemicals, however, has fallen ?.5 percent in the recent past.
Thus, expenditures for pollution control may be of greater relative
significance than in other industries where rising orices more readily
absorb increased costs.

     Regional  growth rates reflect a continuing trend to move produc-
tion facilities closer tc rav materials and markets.  The industry,
as a whole, is  tending to concentrate in the Midwest and Southwest.

     Inorganic  chemical plants vary greatly in size, level of tech-
nology,  product mix, and  age.  The report presents in considerable
detail the description of the various production processes, the wast*
treatment methods practiced, and the possible imoact that changes in
processes might have on the volume and character of the wastes pro-
duced.   A typical or average plant exists only in the statistical
sense.   Total  costs given in the resort are for the construction and
operation of waste treatment facilities for the industry as a whole,
and cannot be used to  determine costs for individual plants.  The
costs given are for the waste treatment facilities only, and do not
include  costs entailed in process changes,  restriction of plant
operations, or sever segregation.  Treatment system construction and
operating costs for a  particular olant can only be estimated by de-
tailed engineering studies.

     Projections based upon the chemical  industry data in the 1963
Census of Manufactures, the 1P67 wanufacturina Chemists Association
survey,  the l°f^ FWPCA study of the organic chemicals industry, and
the costs of treatment for the two levels of ?7*  (the current r?te of
removal, according to  the VCA) and 100'!' removal of contaminants show
the following projected operating costs and cumulative capital invest-
ment for wastewater treatment.
                                   22

-------
                              TABLE 10

        PROJECTED CUMULATIVE INORGANIC CHEMICAL INDUSTRY CAPITAL
                       COSTS FOR WASTE TREATMENT

                       Costs in Millions of Current Dollars -
Removal      1969      1970      1971

   27       299.3      325.4    359.9

  100      1308.4     1964.0   2173.2
                              1072

                              400.1

                             2416.3    2689.0   2970.0
        PROJECTED INORGANIC CHEMICAL INDUSTRY ANNUAL OPERATING
                      COSTS FOR WASTE TREATMENT

                      Costs in Millions of Current Dollars -
 Removal
    27
   100
 1969
 82.0

157.5
1970

 89.1
171.0
1971
1972
1973
1974
 98.6    109.6    122.0    135.5
189.2    210.5    234.2    260.2
 ]_/   Based on an average 3.6£ annual
     anticipated growth.
                        increase in the price level plus
      Contaminated wastewater  from  the  inorganic  chemicals  industry^
 comes primarily  from electrolysis  and  crystallization  brines, washings
 from filter  cakes, spent  acid and  alkalies,  and  washings from raw
 materials.   These wastewaters are  generally  characterized  by dissolved
 solids and suspended solids.   In addition  to contaminated  waste  streams,
 process cooling  discharges  occur,  accounting for 40  to 30% of the  total
 discharge on the average.   Treatment practices  vary  but involve  in-
 plant segregation of contaminated  wastes  from uncontaminated cooling
 waters.  Equalization,  neutralization, sedimentation and lagooning
 processes are most widely used.  Biological  treatment is not^applicable,
 since the contaminants  are  primarily dissolved or suspended inorganic
 materials.   Plants with small discharges  tend to employ only equali-
 zation and neutralization,  with  total  discharge to municipal sewer
 systems for  joint  treatment.   It is estimated that between 10 and  20?,
 of the process wastewater discharge of the industry  is to  municipal
 systems (4.2% of the  total  discharge).  Mo significant percentage
 changes in this  regard  are expected through 1974. The inorganic
 chemicals industry  has  generally found that in-plant, separate  treat-
 ment has economic  advantages, particularly when significant quantities
 of wastewater are  involved.
                                   23

-------
     Data *rom F°  inorganic  chemicals  plants v.'ere obtained and for-
matted according to the  Industrial Waste Treatment Practices Data
ronr, which was developed  for  the study "The Cost of Clean Water and
Its Economic  Impact, Volume  IV,"  United States  Department of the
Interior, January, 1°6°.   The  data obtained are'given  in some detail
in the report in terms of  bar  graphs and various calculated parameters
relating wastewater volumes, plant production, and costs.

     Key parameters of interest,  regarding waste  treatment costs are
the following:

Average capital cost
Average operating  cost/yr.
Average wastewater flow
Average capital cost
Average operating  cost
                                              gpd
                                                grd
                                      16.73  gpd/anrual ton of production
                                     ^3.74/annual ton of production
                                     SC.°8 per year/annual ten of
                                      production
     An examination  of  the  survey  data  showed  that the reported bases
of waste  treatment decisions were  generally  least cost, or minimum
compliance with  pollution control  regulations.

     The  costs of unit  wastev/ater  treatment  methods were developed and
are presented in the report as  a series of mathematical models and cost
function  graphs.  These data were  used  to calculate capital costs of
waste treatment  facilities  versus  two levels of pollutant removal for
a series  of  typical  plants.  Treatment  level I was chosen because it.
represents the reoorted average treatment employed in the industry
at this time and is  judged  to be eauivalent  to '7 1 removal of
suspended and dissolved solids.  Treatment level II represents complete
removal of contaminants.  Only  two levels were selected, because the
industry's wastes are principally  inorganic  solids t^at respond only to
physical  treatment processes.   Because  there are no intervening
technologies, intermediate  levels  of efficiency are not distinguished.
The two levels, then, may be viev.'ed as  a range bounded on the one
side by the current  level of efficiency and  on the other by universal
application of exotic treatment practices.   An almost infinite number
of intermediate Positions are possible within  the range, but only as
the conditions that  ar>r>ly to individual units  of the population change.
I'nlike the case of organic  wastes,  there is  no series of technological
plateaus through which  the  whole population may progress.

     The following summarizes the  capital and  operating costs in
     dollars for the two levels of treatment choser:
  Removal  Contaminants

     ?7 (SS and Acidity)

    100  (TDS)
                              Capital Cost
                                  OOP gnd

                                   300

                                  21 ?5
Operating Cost
   C/1000. gal
      51.5
                                  24

-------
                 DEVELOPMENT OF INVESTMENT NEEDS

     It is widely recognized that the pollution control  effort, in
spite of the advances made in the last fifteen years, is inadequately
funded, but there is a high level of uncertainty with respect to what
may be an appropriate amount of funding.

     That uncertainty must be ascribed to two factors, an inadequate
grasp of the constituents of demand and failure to establish a time
frame.  The question that is most often posed is "how much must we
invest?"  That question cannot be answered unless we establish finite
terms of accomplishment—including both a time schedule  and a pre-
vailing level  of control  of public wastes.  It must be recognized,
too,"that the  terms  of accomplishment cannot be fixed indefinitely.
One time period is  followed by another; and the necessities of control
levels will be dictated by successive economic and population situa-
tions, by the  dynamics of technological capabilities, by the effective
public preference for unpolluted water; and these will--as they bear
upon investment—be  conditioned by price  level changes.

     Recognizing that problems of definition have tended to obscure
every assessment of  investment need that  has been nade in the past, the
economic staff of the Federal  Water Pollution Control Administration
devoted a major portion of its efforts during 1969 to isolating
and examining  the major constituents of public waste-handling invest-
ment behavior.   While subsidiary questions—notably the  trend of real
construction costs over tine and regional variation in unit costs —
force themselves to  attention, the prime  focus of the study was the
rate of formation of demand for waste-handling capital.

     The result of that year of study—which depended heavily on the
previous analyses reported upon in The Cost of Clean Hater (January,
1968) and The  Cost of Clean Water and its Economic Impact (January,
1969) as well  as upon supplemental studies conducted in  the Federal
Water Pollution Control Administration and elsewhere—is the conclusion
that the nation is currently forming demands for public  investment
capital at a rate very close to a billion dollars a year.  Under the
existing set of technological  competences and regulatory conditions,
the level  of waste treatment required of local governments implies
the expenditure of about  a billion dollars a year in addition to any
amount that must be  invested to get the current stock of capital up
to the stipulated level of v/aste treatment.
                                  25

-------
                         An Evaluation Model

     The evaluation is significant enough to warrant a generalized
description of the analysis upon which its rests, even at the risk of
some tedium.

     Two analytical procedures were conducted in parallel, one based
upon normative influences, the other upon recorded situations.  The
basic analytical tool was, in either instance, the same, a mathematical
simulation of investment in public waste handling systems.

     Extremely simple in concept, that mathematical modelling of the
value of physical capital has proved to be very complex in the con-
struction.  Indeed, at this writing it remains a crude—but hopefully
reliable—evaluation technique that is still undergoing extensive
refinement.  In  its present form, the model correlates a series of
equations that define size to average cost relationships (in constant
dollars) for basic waste-handling procedures and equipment with the
current f-junicipal Waste Inventory.  Two separate modelling programs
are employed.  One involves scanning the inventory and assessing
for each recorded sewerage system the cost of constructing or installing
component elements—other than collecting sewers—of the size and
description of those included in the system.  The second program
ignores—except  for their sizing qualities—installed facilities.
It scans the inventory for the needs recorded by the State governments
who are the prime source of the Municipal Waste Inventory.  For each
category of need, the program calculates the average cost of installing
or constructing  the particular facilities—sized according to a normal
statistical distribution of capacity to indicated load.

     The aggregated results for the two programs are presented in
both constant and September, 1969 dollars in Table 11.

                       The Analytical Procedures

     The fact that $4.4 billion worth of needed improvements were
listed in the most recent compilation of public waste handling systems
is of less than  conclusive importance, in that it does not reflect
the development  of such needs.  It does not mirror the formative
imperatives of time, change, economic growth; the fact that as one
set of conditions is met, new problems arise—or are created by the
resolution of the old ones.

     The rate of formation of such needs must be understood if a pur-
poseful  program of investment in water pollution control is to be
formulated.   The evaluation model, with the introduction of the element
of time,  provides enough information to define at least an order of
magnitude view of annual  investment needs development.
                                   26

-------
                                     TABLE  11
             Evaluation of  Capital  in  Place  and  of  Defined Needs,  1969
Alabama
Alaska
Arizona
Arkansas
California
Colorado
Connecticut
Delaware
District of Columbia
Florida
Georgia
Hawaii
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Maine
Maryland
Massachusetts
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
New Hampshire
New Jersey
New Mexico
New York
 North Carolina
 North Dakota
Ohio
 Oklahoma
 Oregon
 Pennsylvania
 Rhode Island
 South Carolina
 South Dakota
 Tennessee
 Texas
 Utah
 Vermont
 Virginia
 Washington
 West Virginia
 Wisconsin
 Wyoming
 Puerto Rico
 Virgin Islands

        Totals
                          Value of Works  in  Place
1957-59
Dollars

 139.0
   1.1
  45.6
 107.0
 769.1
 165.9
  89.0
  25.0
  33.6
 312.4
 204.2
  16.8
  58.0
 497.2
 313.0
     .3
     .2
     .3
     .2
206.5
184.5
140.5
140.1
 17.9
 88.
102.
252.
205.
109.9
229.0
 54.7
124.0
 29.6
 16.3
304.4
 7.1.6
580.4
248.3
 56.4
  484,
  171.
  124,
  424.2
   38.1
  113.1
   58
  168
  639
   87
   20.8
  166.
  143,
   73.9
  254,
   38.
   34.1
 8979.7
                                         Current
                                         Dollars
              191.8
                1.5
               62.9
              147.7
             1061.4
              228.9
              122.8
.5
.4
.1
.8
.2
.0
 34
 46
431
281
 23
 80
686.1
431.9
285.9
254.6
193.9
193
 24
121
141
348
283
    3
    7
    9
    0
    2
    2
151.7
316.0
 75.5
171.1
 40.8
 22.5
420.1
 98.8
801.0
342.7
 77.8
.9
.9
.7
.4
                  .0
                  .5
 668.
 236.
 171
 585.
  52.6
 156.1
  81,
 232.
 882.0
 120.8
  28.7
 229.4
 197.6
 102.0
 350.9
  52.7
  47.1
             12392.0
                                  Value of Needed Works
                    .2
                    .3
                    .3
                    .2
                                 1957-59
                                 Dollars
                 89.0
                  6.0
                 14.8
                 32
                273
                 31
                 53
                  2.5
                 20.4
                 35.1
                 89.7
                 18.8
                 24.3
                141.2
                100.9
                 32.1
                 59.8
                 11.8
                 57.4
                 66
                 20
                151
                 98
                 39
                 36
                                    107.8
                                       .4
                                       .7
                                       .3
                  16.
                  27.
                  12.
                  44.6
                 117.4
                   7.4
                 200.0
                  73.7
                   4.8
                 166.6
                  23.0
                  46.5
                 262.5
                   16.6
                   48.5
                   10.0
                   52.0
                  117.0
                   20.3
                   29.6
                                      .5
                                      .3
                                      .3
                                      .2
                   47.
                   65.
                   54.
                   90.
                    6.4
                   23.6
                    2.7

                 3201.1
                              Current
                              Dollars
122.8
  8.3
 20.
 44.
377.2
 43.2
 73.4
  3.5
 28.
 48.
123.8
 25.9
 33.5
194.9
                                      .4
                                      .6
                                                    .2
                                                    .4'
                                   .2
                                   ,3
                                   .5
                                   .3
                                   .2
                                   .8
                                   .3
                                   .2
 139.
  44,
  82.
  16.
  79.
  91,
  28.
 209.
 135.7
  54.4
  50.0
 148.8
  22.6
  38.2
  17.0
  61.5
 162.0
  10.2
 276.0
 101.7
   6.6
 229.9
  31,
  64.
 362.
  22.
  66.
  13.8
  71.8
 161.5
  28.0
  40.8
  65.6
  90.1
  74.9
 124.5
   8.8
  32.6
   3.7

4417.5
                                                    .7
                                                    .2
                                                    .3
                                                    .9
                                                    .9
                                        27

-------
     The first of the two procedures used to determine the rate of
formation of demand for investment capital consisted of a simple
comparision of recorded needs over time, applying the same modelling
procedures to the 1962 Municipal Waste Inventory that were used to
evaluate the 1968 Inventory, and taking into account the investment
that occurred between inventories.  The analysis took the form:

                       A =  (X - Y) + I
                                T

Where:  A= average annual investment demand developed during the period,
        X= investment demand, as defined by the Inventory at the begin-
           ning of the period,
        Y= investment demand at the end of the period,
        1= actual investment, adjusted to base period prices, over the
           period,
        T= number of years  between inventories.

     It is recognized that  there is a measure of over-simplification
in the equation.  It implies an effective identity of replacement with
depreciation, not at all a  good assumption in a period like the present
when most of the physical capital involved is of relatively recent
origin; and it neglects changes in real costs that have occurred be-
tween 1962 and 1968 by evaluating the earlier period's needs in terms
of current cost functions.  The basic formula, however, is considered
to be logical; and adjustments are possible.  Expressed numerically, it
provides a value of about 500 million (1957-59) dollars a year for the
capital requirements posed  by depreciation, grov/th, and system improve-
ment:

                  (3201.1 - 3001.7) + 2759.3 = 493.2
                                    6

     The second analytical  procedure involved the use of normative
standards (rather than regulatory/engineering determinations) in con-
junction with the evaluation model.  Established rates of depreciation
were applied to the estimated replacement value of waste treatment
plants (4% based on a twenty-five year average life), and to the esti-
mated value of ancillary works such as interceptor sewers, outfalls,
pumping stations, and force mains (2%, based on a fifty year average
life—presumably somewhat greater than fifty years for the sewer com-
ponent, somewhat less for other facilities).  In similar fashion,
growth of demand was assessed by projecting a continuation of the rate
of increase in the hydraulic loading of municipal waste-handling systems
that took place in the period 1957 to 1968, or 3.3% a year.

     The exercise produced a set of values that were incredibly close
to those derived from point by point evaluation of recorded needs.  As
presented in Table 12, they show a set of annual investment requirements
rising from $425 million in 1962 to $584 million in 1968.  The average
                                  28

-------
value for the period, $504 million, is within 2.3% of the mean value
developed by the first procedure, and well  within the range lying
within one standard deviation about the mean.

                               Table 12

             Normative Assessment cf Annual Capital Needs
                      Generated in 196? and 1968

                                     Millions of 1957-59'Dollars
                                          1%2          1968

Replacement Value of Trtmt. Plants    2975.2       4132.7
   recapitalization at 4%                   119.0         105.3
Replacement Value of Assctd,  Works    3498.9       4347.0
   recapitalization at 22                    69.8          9G.9
Loading growth at 3.3%                      213.3         296.3
   incremental recapitalization
   for plants to be upgraded at 4%           22.9*         25.5*

Annual Needs developed in year              425.0         534.0

*Value considered to be associated with primary treatment capacity
required to be upgraded to secondary treatment.

                       Elements of the Investment
                              Requirement

     Table 13 summarizes, State by State, the computed value associated
with the various categories of investment needs, as these were listed
in the 196G Municipal Waste Inventory and assessed by the evaluation
model.

     The most obvious needs for investment are posed by those 1500
sewered communities that discharge raw wastes to waterways.  Given the
existing size distribution of those communities, normal design stand-
ards, and the assumption of treatment through the activated sludge
process, these plants pose a need for about $1.4 billion (1957-59 dollars)
of investment—about $950,000 per community, including the investment
in transmission facilities and in outfalls that is probably required
for these communities, on the basis of their size distribution and the
historical relationship between plant and ancillary costs for communities
of various sizes.

     A second fairly clearly defined category of need occurs in those
approximately 2500 situations in v/hich only primary waste treatment
exists.  Although primary treatment is permitted by water quality
standards in some cases due to the capacity of receiving waters to
assimilate wastes, the prevailing policy in the United States has come
to be one that requires secondary treatment.  The consequences of that
policy in terms of investment, then, can be calculated on the basis of


                                  29

-------
                                                   TABLE  13
                     Computed  Values  for Various  Categories  of Investment Needs by State
                                         Millions  of 1957-59 Dollars

              New  Plants   Upgrading   Enlargement   Disinfection   Connection  to      Other
                                                                 Existing System   Improvements
Al attama
Alaska
Ari zona
Arkansas
California
Colorado
Connecticut
Del aware
District of Columbia
Florida
Georgia
Hawaii
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Maine
Maryland
Massachusetts
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
Mew Hampshire
Hew Jersey
Hew Mexico
New York
North Carolina
North Dakota
Ohio
Oklahoma
Oregon
Pennsylvania
Rhode Island
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Utah
Vermont
Virginia
Washington
West Virginia
Wisconsin
Wyoming
Puerto Rico
Virgin Islands
$75.35
4.32
10.80
9.29
16.40
5.86
6.86
0.32

0.72
36.41
12.62
8.47
22.67
32.14
9.84
40.19
3.86
41.65
60.57
2.29
88.50
19.83
7.21
28.00
98.19
5.65
12.35
3.62
40.18

1.75
103.19
49.37
4.09
30.81
4.35
15.88
190.93
4.35
42.84
6.50
21.89
3.06
11.46
18.23
5.80
7.82
37.99
0.91
4.47
14.06
2.66
$5.95
1.66
0.20
10.54
61.44
5.40
39.22
2. IB

0.89
21.59
1.20
10.44
56.88
12.22
2.29
9.03
6.81
4.18
5.79
2.97
22.63
61.44
26.92
1.09
5.01
9.09
12.34
4.65
0.56
101.67
2.79
92.17
13.10
0.73
78.61
11.09
13.56
36.05
3.14
4.08
2.52
28.54
20.97
1.77
10.52
21.97
17.40
16.26
73.29
1.31
9.52

$7.62

3.76
6.89
181.47
19.96
4.45

20.38
33.46
22.81
0.61
4.63
49.52
46.43
16.07
10.33
1,04
11.53

12.37
12.46
12.30
2.44
7.13
4.28
1.49
2.94
4.06
3.87
15.73
2.87
4.65
9.94

48.55
6.05
14.50
33.48
2.55
1.61
0.32
1.56
93.01
7.04
0.83
2.51
14.21

9.36
0.48


                                                      $0.09
                                                       0.51
                                                       2.82
                                                       6.39
                                                       3.93

                                                       0.14
                                                       0.12
                                                       0.11
                                                       0.01
                                                       0.02
                                                       0.01
Totals
               $U86.56    $965.67
$773.55
                                                       3.58

                                                       0.29
                                                       0.24
                                                       0.66
                                                        0.02
                                                        0.43

                                                        0.53
                                                        0.16
$20.06
                              $5.59
                              13.%

                               2.64
                               8.06
                               4.34

                               9.25
                               3.68
                               0.13
                               2.76
                              26.30
                               3.90
                               2.74
                               1.17

                               5,07
                               1.50
                               2.01
                               1.80
                               0.15
                               17.18
                               25.32

                                6.13
$143.68
                                                                                     $0.12

                                                                                     0.05
                                0.31

                                0.78
                                0,03
                                              0.22

                                              0.02
                                1.64
                                0,31
                                0.02

                                0.30
                                0.16
                                0.09
                                                                                      0.02

                                                                                      0.17
                                0.03
                                0.23
                                0.04
                                6.37
                                0.01

                                0.02
                                0.02
                                0.12
$11.60
Total

$89.03
5.98
14.81
32.32
273. 27
31.30
53.16
2.51
20.38
35.07
87.70
18.78
24. 3Z
141.15
100.86
32.14
57.77
11.84
57.38
66.49
20.51
151.64
98.29
39.35
36.23
107.78
16.40
27.12
12.33
44.61
117.41
7.42
200.01
73.72
4.83
166.62
23.02
46.46
262.52
16.57
48.54
10.00
52.01
117.04
20.27
29.58
47.51
65.30
54.25
90.23
6.42
23.59
2.66
One Standard
Deviation
313.44
1.40
1.99
7.77
17.41
5.14
6.45
0.43
11.37
4.94
10.20
2.86
3.18
15.36
8.92
4.32
20.75
3.63
19.25
19.17
7.54
37.01
10.95
10.14
9.55
31.85
3.34
4.08
1.54
10.38
15.59
0.95
50.67
9.00
0.48
14.51
3.08
5.63
57.25
2.33
5.77
1.04
11.97
7.62
1.84
4.94
6.24
9.85
8.81
7.76
2.14
6.10
1.26
                                                                                                $3201.12
                                                                      $539.19
                                                      30

-------
historical  cost factors to require an investment of about $900 million
of (1957-59)  dollars, or an average of $360,000 per project.

     Another  $800 million worth of miscellaneous kinds of projects
completes the list of current needs.  In total, they indicate a most
likely investment need of $3.1  billion in a range of $2.6 billion to
$3.7 billion  constant dollars—or, in current dollar terms, a most
likely investment need for 4.4  billion September, 1969 dollars in a
range of $3.6 billion to $5.0 billion.

     But this fixed,  presumably diminishing with time, set of values
represents  no more than a point on a scale.  They are the cur-^t com-
bination of those dynamic elements that underlie basic demand ! ,r
capital  in  this economic sector.   Those elements will persist; and even
a vigorous  public effort to reduce the accumulatic  of investment re-
quirements  will not end the continuing need for capital.  Indeed; as
the waste-producing qualities of our growing economy assert themselves,
the annual  capital requirements of the waste-controlling activity may
be expected to increase.

     It is  not paradoxical that requirements expand as our level  of
controls expand.   Before a facility is constructed its need represents
a contingent  liability:  once built, it must be kept in operating
condition,  modernized, expanded,  upgraded to meet conditions.  Such
investment  requirements may be less obvious and less dramatic than the
need for a  plant where none exists,  but they are no less real--and are
often far less postponable.  It follows, then, that as the level  of
waste control grows,  so does the magnitude of the annual investment
associated  with waste control.  There is no better means of demonstrating
the compounding effect of past investments'on future needs than to
review the  recorded needs associated with sewer f/sterns at each of the
last three  municipal  waste inventories,  (cf. Tab e 14.)  While the
number of persons attached to sewers increased fo; ty-two percent
between 1957  and 1968, the raw number of recorded investment needs
increased ninety-two  percent.  A different kind of investment require-
ment was engaged—various major and minor ungrading projects steadily
replacing new plant needs over time—but both the total number of
needed projects and the number of persons affected has risen.

     Rising investment demand,  then, is not only consistent with the
general  rules for a growing economy, but equally consistent with the
pattern of  events in  the particular economic sector under consideration.
Moreover, it  is possible to distinguish the influences that form that
demand.  They  may, for purposes of discussion, be considered under four
general  categories:  1) recapitalization, 2) growth, 3) prices, and
4) "changes in the rules of the game."
                                  31

-------
GJ
ro
                                                   TABLE  14
                                     Increase In State Government-Defined
                                       Waste Treatment Needs Over Time*
       Kind of Need
                               Number of Systems

                           1957      1962      19C8
New Plants
Replacement
Enlargement
Additional Treatment
Chiorination
Improved Operation
Connection

Total Mo. Needs
Total Systems
  % w needs

New Facilities I/
Major Upgrading |/
Minor Upgrading ^/

*Source:  Municipal Waste Inventory, 1957, 1962, 1968

!_/  New Plant, replacement, connection
2/  Enlargement, additional treatment
_3/  Chlorlnation, improved operation
2549
973
688
753
41
329
57
5390
10,511
51.3
3579
1441
370
2143
853
809
821
42
332
45
5045
11,006
45.8
3311
3071
374
1586
625
1003
2130
723
209
123
6399
13,849
46.2
2334
3133
932
                                                                       1957
Population Served
     (OOO's)
       1962
1968
13,504.0
3,101.6
15,315.9
7,687.0
598.1
887.3
676.4
41,770.3
98,361.9
42.5
17,282.0
23,002.9
1,485.4
13,058.4
3,888.2
24,849.0
8,215.8
201.4
1,068.2
482.3
51,763.3
118,371.9
43.7
17,428.9
33,064.8
1,269.6
9,575.3
1,719.9
27,861.6
36,327.5
2,937.8
888.8
1,019.7
80,330.6
139,726.7
57.5
12,314.9
64,099.1
3,826.6

-------
                          Recapitalization

     Table 12 presents an effort to quantify and evaluate the dimensions
of annual  recapitalization needs as they exist in mid-1969.   The
constant dollar replacement value of all public waste transmission
and treatment facilities is calculated to be about $3.9 billion.
In the real  world, recapitalization needs tend to occur in staggered
fashion, so that investments for any particular system (except, perhaps,
for a few of the very largest)  are characterized by a considerable
lumpiness.  For the aggregate system of the nation, however, it is
reasonable to assume that recapitalization needs will reflect in
fairly precise measure normal design standards.  The analysis, then,
has assigned a replacement factor of four percent for treatment plants
and two percent for ancillary works, adopting as points of departure
the twenty-five year and fifty year design lives that civil  engineers
ascribe to such facilities. Basic physical capital, then, is depreciating
at a combined rate of about 2.9% a year.  In 1969, the calculated
recapitalization need created amounted to about $260 million 1957-59
dollars.

     Misconceptions often surround the theory of depreciation or
replacement.  As these factors  are viewed in this paper—and as they
occur in the real  world—they apply as a series of intermittent invest-
ments that duplicate the original cost of an installed facility within
a given period of time.   Recapitalization factors, then, are not
intended to  reflect some theoretical wearing out or mere bookkeeping
transactions; they represent tangible outlays incurred in connection
with existing facilities.

     (There  may be some  question about the accuracy of the assigned
depreciation rates.  They depend on design factors rather than
empirical  data.  Information on replacement is scarce, and its inter-
pretation is obscured by the overlap of replacement, upgrading, and
improvement  that, is involved in the usual project that involves an
installed facility.  The information that we do have—covering just
over ten percent of all  recorded sewerage systems--!ndicates that ten
percent of all plants undergo a major revision within five years of
their construction date; and that within fifteen years of their con-
struction, forty-five percent of all plants undergo some major revision.
(cf. Table TS.)  On this basis, the four percent recapitalization
factor is, if anything,  conservative.)

                             Growth

     The growth rate built into the calculation of annual investment
need is high, indicating a demand for capacity that is compounding at
3.3 percent per year.  The rate is based on recorded increases in
average daily flow between 1957 and 1968.  It includes both the period
of maximum treatment plant construction in the nation's history, and
more recent intensive industrial connections to public facilities.


                                  33

-------
co
                                                  TABLE 15
                                Frequency of Major Treatment Plant Revisions
Last
Revision
Since


1963
1958
1953
1948
1943
1938
1933
No. Of
Plants
Identified Plant Built


775
453
133
36
3
4
2

1964-68 1959-63 1954-58 1949-53 1944-48
78 153 118 67 21
30 51 42 15
9 11 4
2




1939-43
119
84
32
8
1



1934-38
103
85
27
8
2



1929-33
54
56
23
7


1

1928 or
before
62
90
26
11

4
1
       TOTALS       1406         78      183      178      120       42      244      225      141      194

-------
It may be expected to moderate in the future.  This paper, however,
relates only to needs to be anticipated over the next five to ten
years; and within that time frame, there is no reason to expect a de-
cline in the rate of growth.  If anything, the trend toward broader
industrial connections may effectuate an interim increase in the
growth of demand.

     There are three processes of accommodating growth.  Newly sewered
communities or subdivisions—wholly new sewer systems—are the least
significant source of demand, though they are also the easiest to
quantify.  On average, about 230 new sewer systems come into being in
the United States every year.  The second, and more significant, growth
process involves an expanded demand on an existing system.  In this
case, newly sewered residential areas or newly connected factories add
their demands to those of a system already in place.  They can be
accommodated in either of tv/o ways, either through the construction of
new facilities or by taking up previously unused capacity provided to
accommodate just such growth. In either of these last two conditions,
growth will ultimately require construction.  Indeed, the first case,
where additional capacity must be installed, is simply an extension in
time of the second.  Growth can be accommodated in an existing plant
to the point that all capacity is taken up; at that point, an investment
need is created.

     Because it is customary to design plants to provide for the
growth of service anticipated within the life of the plant—normally a
period of twenty-five years—most of the $300 million a year need for
expansion is currently being met out of existing capacity.  Since the
age composition of the nation's stock of treatment plants is  con-
ditioned by high investment in the last decade, the nation has been
able to continue to extend its total level of waste control over the
last few years.  It should be noted, however, that not all of the
capacity now available for growth will be usable within the normal
life of the present stock of plants.  Almost all waste treatment plants
are built to accommodate enlarged demands, but not all communities
grow.  The naive projection techniques employed by consulting engineers
have tended to create a pool of excess capacity that will never be used
in small, static communities.  Conversely, treatment plants built to
conventional sizing standards in other places have proved entirely
inadequate to meet the demands of recent industrial connections.  The
aggregate supply of treatment services probably exceeds the aggregate
demand for such services.  Unfortunately, the supoly is not entirely
located at the same places as is the demand; and with  time, the dis-
location will become more significant.  That fact  is one of the
pressing reasons for increasing the level of investment in public waste
handling facilities at the earliest possible date.
                                   35

-------
                              Prices

      One  of the  central  economic  perceptions  of  the  last  five years.
 has  been  grov/ing discomfort  caused by price  increases; prices have
 been rising at accelerating  rates.

      For  municipalities, with their ultimate  responsibility for  instal-
 ling and  operating waste handling systems,  increased prices have
 entailed  a more  direct constraint on pollution abatement  activities
 than have more substantive national  economic  problems.  Business cycle
 fluctuations,  structural unemployment, and  accommodation  of a grov/ing
 labor force have impinged on the  operations  and  finances  of local
 government, but  only indirectly.   But the resumption of the rate of
 price increases  experienced  in the nineteen-fifties  has had an enormous
 impact on local  government funding capacities.   Even during the  rela-
 tive respite from inflationary pressures  experienced from I960 through
 1064, county and municipal governments were  unable to meet out of rela-
 tively inflexible tax bases  increasing pressures of  real  demand  for
 social and environmental services.  In that  context  of inadequacy,
 rising prices  have had a serious  effect.  Throughout  the  economy,
 the  only  sector  that has suffered more from  price increases than local
 governments is probably the  very  poor; and even  their difficulties
 stem in part from State and  local governments' losing struggle
 to maintain their share of welfare services.

      It is customary to consider  the problem  of  rising prices rather
 offhandedly as "inflation".   Cut  for local waste handling needs, the
 problem has three aspects; and of these,  inflation has probably  not
 been as serious  in itself as through its  effects on  the cost and
 availability of  money.  While the prices  of labor and materials  consumed
 in constructing  and operating a waste handling system have advanced
 quite steeply, the advance in the cost of monies has had  an even more
 pronounced effect on expenditures, and the scarcity  of funds--
 even at advanced prices—has constrained  capital outlays  for treatment
 and  collection systems even  where willingness to construct was strong.
 Mot  inflation so much as the money rationing  procedures of financial
 markets have reduced local government's ability  to come speedily
 to grips  with its  waste handling  problems.

      It is  difficult to document  the observation except by example,
 since  there  is no  register of bond issue  cancellations or deferrals.
 Examples  are plentiful,  however.   At the  close of its 1969 fiscal year,
 the  State  of California  reported  deferral of  a billion dollars of
 voter-approved bond  issues--80£ of then for financing of water resource
 projects.   Federal Water Pollution Control Administration regional
 offices have reported a  number of instances of postponement of munic-
 ipal  financing of  treatment  works  in cases in which  a Federal grant
 has  been solicited.   The June  8,  1969 issue of The New York Times (1:2)
mentioned  in a feature article  on  the effect  of  interest  rates no less
 than fifteen cases of municipal projects  cancelled or delayed by
                                  36

-------
financial  constraints—and these apparently represented  not an  attempt
at comprehensive reporting, but  simply random examples,  probably  chosen
for their  dramatic nature.  In many cases,  the absolute  shortage  of
funds is reinforced in its impact on local  financing by  statutory
interest rate ceilings or limitations  on  indebtedness.

     While reduction of the relative supply of funds may be the most
serious source of inflationary constraints  on pollution  abatement,
direct effects are not to be slighted.  Over the last twenty years,
the cost of constructing a waste treatment  plant—as measured by  factor
costs—has almost doubled.  Opportunity costs, as measured  by interest
rates, have nearly quadrupled—which,  working on the inflated construc-
tion cost  base, has increased the cost of financing a plant more  than
six-fold.   In combination, these factors  have caused it  to  cost three
times as much to finance and build a waste  treatment plant  today  as the
same plant would have cost in 1950; and half of that increase in  cost
has taken  place in the last five years,  (cf. Table 16).

                              TABLE 16

               Escalation of the Cost of  A  $1,000,000
                  Waste Treatment Plant,  1950-1959

Year Interest  Const. Cost  Cost Rise over Previous Period  Total  Cost
        Rate*     Index**     Interest      Construction    (25 yrs.)
1950
1955
1960
1965
1967
1968
1969
1.
2.
3.
3.
3.
56
18
26
16
74
4.28
5.91
 69
 89
105
113
120
124
132
148,350
276,050
 28,400
165,650
149,550
448,000
Cumulative Cost Increases    $1,216,000

* Moody's State and Local Aaa, June 30.
** Sewage Treatment Plant Cost Index, FWPCA
$260,000
 260,000
 120,000
 100,000
  60,000
 110,000

$910,000
$1,195,000
 1,603,350
 2,139,400
 2,287,800
 2,553,450
 2,763,000
 3,321,000

$2,126,000
     Those increases can be quantified and projected for our evaluation
model.  The $3.2 billion evaluation of current year investment require-
ments amounts to $4.4 billion when base year costs are escalated to
September, 1969 price levels, and it is only reasonable to assume
further increases in prices.  Over the last five years the annual in-
crease in factor costs has amounted to 3.2% to 3.7%; and this paper
will project future costs to include a 3.5% annual cost increase co-
efficient.

                   Changes in The Rules of the Game

     The area of evaluation that presents the greatest difficulty is
                                  37

-------
the problem of definition.  The evaluation model, and the proposed
investment schedule developed at a later point in this paper, rest
upon a given set of conditions, the rules of the game as it is general-
ly played today.  But there is nothing sacred about those rules^-today's
are very different than those of five years ago, for example—and any
basic change must have a fundamental effect on investment conditions.

     Some possible changes are almost predictable.  There is, for
example, a very pronounced tendency to require treatment of sewage for
removal of phosphate.  No price tag has been attached to that type of
treatment in this paper for two reasons:  at this time, phosohate
removal is a specialized and  localized kind of requirement; and there is
no preferred—or even accepted—technique of accomplishing it.  The most
likely treatment methods appear to involve very slight incremental
investments, but extremely large increases in operating costs for
purchase of chemical additives.  Should a capital-intensive method of
treatment become available, should phosphate removal become a universal
requirement, investment requirements might be expected to shift power-
fully upward.   Conversely, if soap producers were to find an acceptable
alternative for phosphorus-based detergents (and there is increasing
pressure in western Europe to require such a course), then this partic-
ular influence  on costs might diminish.

     An example of the way in which a shift in the rules of the game
has already influenced costs  may be adduced by reference to Table 14.
Between 1957 and 1962, the total number of needs associated with public
sewerage systems declined, in spite of an increase in the number of
systems.  Between 1962 and 1968, however, needs increased sharoly,
even though investments were  much greater between those years than in
the preceding period.  Interposition of water quality standards and
application of  the secondary  waste treatment requirement, a major
change in the rules, created  an entirely new definition of what might
constitute a need, forcing required investment levels sharoly upward.

      Nor are changes always  determined administratively, or applied
across the board.  The internal pressures of engineering practice
condition the rules of cost;  and local preference may dictate specialized
sets of rules.

     Engineering practice has certainly been changing as money has be-
come increasingly available for water pollution control investments.
There has been  a growing tendency to use the more expensive of the
secondary waste treatment processes, to construct plants of larger
size relative to current loading demand, and to utilize additional
mechanical operating components.  Treatment plants that are being
built today are quite different from those of a decade ago in a number
of ways.  The underlying technology is the same, including a mixture
of physical and biochemical reactions that take place in a series of
tanks connected by piping and pumping; but there has been a strong
effort to improve the engineering of those reactions, to build into
                                  38

-------
facilities greater reliability and longer life.   More stages are
automated.  Monitoring has become more sophisticated.  More durable
materials are being employed.   Much more attention is being paid to
sludge handling and incineration  is being employed in a growing number
of instances.  As a result, the cost of treatment systems has been
going up, quite apart from price level increases.  Indeed, the increase
in real costs has matched or exceeded the increase suffered as a result
of inflation over the last five or six years,  judging from a statistical
study of comparative pricing patterns in 1961-63 and in 1967-69. (R.L.
Michels: Construction Costs of Municipal Wastewater Treatment Plants,
1967-69 .) In terms of construction put in place between 1962 and 1968,
those increases in real costs  are estimated to have added about $400
million to the investment associated with waste treatment plant
construction.
                              TABLE 17

                Constant Dollar Investment Per Unit Capacity
                 Activated Sludge Plant, 1961-63 and 1967-69

Capacity of Plant                 Investment/P.E.  Capacity ($1957-59)
  (Pop. Eqvlts.)                    1961-63            1967-69

     1,000                           66.00             87.50
    10,000                           29.50             43.00
   100,000                           13.00             21.50

     The effects of local  preference can result in substantial differ-
ences in waste treatment investment.  The water quality standards
adopted by the State of Indiana call for the construction of 45 advanced
waste treatment plants—representing the majority of the standards-
required advanced waste treatment needs for the entire United States.
In the western States, waste stabilization ponds are the most prevalent
treatment measure; and the low cost installations serve to reduce
unit costs to a fraction of the amount required by mechanical treatment
plants.  In the Northeast, however, such facilities are almost unknown.
In the Southwest, the treatment of industrial wastes in municipal
facilities is a rarity; in the Pacific Northwest, and increasingly
in New England, it is becoming standard practice.  New York and New
Jersey, in connection with their extremely vigorous pollution control
programs, seem to be engaged in major rehabilitation of sewerage
systems already in place, scheduling very large sums for replacement
and integration of existing facilities.  Without casting judgements
on the relative effectiveness of these or other expressions of differing
local interpretations of the rules of the game, one can conclude
that they have an enormous power to influence investment totals.
                                  39

-------
                 Locational Influences on Plant Cost

     Reported investment data, when related to municipal waste treat-
ment inventories, indicate  that there are enormous differences between
regions of the United States  in the capital efficiency of public
waste-handling.

     Setween 196? and 1%8, local governmental units invested, on
average, about $120  for each  person reported to be added to a public
sewer  system.  About $187 more was invested in waste treatment and
transmission for each additional  population equivalent of biochemical
oxygen  demand from domestic sources that was reduced in wastn handling
systems.  (The figures are  not adjusted for additions or subtractions
from excess capacity.  They wore  derived by dividing total investments
made in the period 1962 to  1967 by the  incremental waste collection
and reduction calculated to be achieved during the same period.  To the
extent  that total capacity  was increased beyond the level of actively
utilized capacity and to the  extent that wastes from industrial sources
were added to the system, unit investments are overstated.  They do,
however, provide an  adequate  measure  for comparison of regional expend-
itures, since they weigh on a consistent basis the investment
associated with an homogeneous incremental product.)  Application of
the technique to investments  made by  blocks of States thought to be
economically, politically,  and goonrnphically similar produced results
that point to wide regional variations  in waste handling costs.  At the
extremes, it cost $2.75 in  the highest  cost area to buy the incremental
v/aste  handling effectiveness  purchased  for a dollar in the lowest.

     The numerical results  of the analysis are not reproduced here for
several reasons.  It is recognized that the basic data are not in all
respects compatible  or reliable.  The analysis concerns itself with
total  costs but incremental efficiencies in a situation where much
of the  investment that was  made is recognized to have been for purposes
of replacement rather than  for new or upgraded facilities.  Differing
regional propensities to treat industrial wastes have a distorting
effect on results.   And by  the very nature of the analysis, regions
with high rates of population growth  tend to appear distinctly more
efficient, in that their more rapid uptake of excess capacity has the
effect of applying a lov/er  apparent rate of discount.  To describe
unit cost differences under these conditions might be thought to stig-
matize unfairly the  regulatory or construction competencies of the
higher cost areas; and the  results of the analyses are felt to be too
hazy in detail to be presented in quantitative forms.  However, the
conclusion that unit costs  vary substantially with location is too
firmly founded to be doubted, regardless of definition difficulties.
Moreover, the pattern of difference is quite clear.  Cost rises as one
moves eastward and northward:  they tend to be highest in New England
and States bordering the Great Lakes, lowest in the southwestern and
Gulf Coast States.    (Groups of States are ranked according to relative
costs at several points in  the discussion that follows, and the com-
position of the various groupings is defined in Figure 2.)

                                  40

-------
                             Figure 2
          Regional Definitions for Analysis of
       Comparative Unit Investment for Incremental
       Waste-Handling Capabilities, 1962-1968
                               GREAT LAKES
SOUTHWEST
                                           SOUTHEAST
                                                                            ENGLAND
        NORTH ATLANTIC

        Q
  rMIDDLE ATLANTIC
1* **'      •

-------
      Examination of investment programs on an aggregate basis  has
 failed to produce satisfactory explanations of cost differentials  of
 the magnitude indicated. A number of possible explanations  have  been
 adduced by the analytical staff and by observers in Federal  Water
 Pollution Control Administration regional  offices,  State government,
 and the consulting engineering industry.  In some cases, information
 was available to allow a proposed explanation to be tested  in  broad
 fashion.  In some cases, the reason proposed for cost  differences  was
 so intangible or so illogical (e.g., criminal domination of  construc-
 tion activities) as to allow it to be discarded, even  when  investigation
 could not be attempted.  A number of very  reasonable propositions
 remained after preliminary consideration eliminated the obviously
 misdirected and the intangible; but whether any of these, or any combin-
 ation of them, accounts fully for the spread in observable  returns on
 investment remained a problem.  The array  of proposed  explanations of
 unit investment differences presented from various  sources  included
 all of the following:

       (1)  Data deficiencies. Information  on the prevalence  and  methods
 of waste treatment and on population connected to public sewers  is re-
 ported individually by the States.  Although a common  format is  utilized,
 there is great variation in estimating techniques employed  and in  the
 completeness of reports.  Similarly, investment data is gathered direct-
 ly from State agencies, as well as from various economic reporting
 services, so variation in reporting practices may influence  results.  It
 should be noted, however, that unit cost variation  within any  of the
 groups of States considered was consistently found  to  be less  than
 between the various groups, so that anomalies attributable  to  data
 variability must be presumed to include regionally  consistent  reporting
 deviations.

      There is, in addition, independent analytical  work that suggests
 that regional  cost differences are a very  real phenomenon,  and not the
 result of reporting freaks.  The State of  New York, through  the  operations
 of its grant programs, has compiled a great deal of information  on the
 capital  cost of waste treatment facilities.  The State's analysis  of that
 information indicates that construction costs in New York State  are
 consistently above national costs—and in  the same  general magnitude
 indicated by FWPCA's  investigation of regional cost variation.

      (2)   Institutional  constraints.   It has been suggested  that design
 practices  that result either from administrative requirements  or local
 habit  strongly influence the relative cost of facilities  in  some loca-
 tions.   The concept must certainly receive some credence.  Those States
 adhering  to the "Ten  State Standards"--i.e., States bordering  the  Great
 Lakes,  Iowa, and  the  New England States—do include the groups that
 account  for high  unit investment requirements.

     Unfortunately, it is  not possible to  come to any  meaningful judge-
ment as  to  the ultimate  affect of such procedures on cost.   While  those
                                  42

-------
responsible for their development will defend the long term economy of
"high standards", the economist will generally deplore rigid standards
in any field as being conducive to formalism and a barrier to innovation
or improvement.

     If one can conclude that institutional constraints do in fact add
to costs in States of the Northeast* it is nonetheless impossible to
assign more than a contributory effect to them.  The effective range of
technical alternatives is simply not so great as to account for the
gross disparity found in regional unit costs.

     (3)  Industrial Loadings.  Authorities in New England have suggested
that one of the principal factors influencing per-capita construction
costs in their region is the high incidence of public agency responsi-
bility for treating wastes of industrial origin.

     There is certainly a rough logic to the explanation, and the figures
tend to bear out the assertion that industrial requirements tend to in-
flate per-capita costs in some areas more than in others.  Because the
capital requirement associated with industrial wastes is influenced by
the quantity of wastewater involved more than by qualitative differences
in treatment procedures, the major impact of addition of manufacturing
wastes to the system can be measured through its impact on plant size.

     Table 18 bears out the fact that treatment plants tend to be larger
with respect to population served in New England than in other areas,
and to be smaller in the Gulf and Southwest areas, v/here unit investments
have been lowest.   However, the table also indicates that greater cap-
acity per unit of population served can by no means be considered the
only—or even a principal—source of higher costs.  While the smallest
capacity to population served ratios occur in the areas of lowest
per-capita costs,  the Pacific Coast and Southeastern States combine low
unit costs with a large median capacity; moreover, these States have
a very significant component of plants in the largest size to populatior
served categories.  In fact, half of the regional groupings (Pacific
Coast, Southeast,  Middle Atlantic, North Atlantic and Ohio-Tennessee)
demonstrate a precisely inverse correlation in a plotting of unit
capacity ranking vs. unit cost ranking.  It is clear, then, that larger
construction costs per person can be only partially explained on the
basis of construction of greater capacity per person.

     (4)  Wage Rates.  It has also been suggested that regional labor
cost differentials have a strong impact on unit costs.  The proposal
has a certain attraction that is dispelled pretty thoroughly
by a review of relative costs and of wage rate differentials.  About
18% of the cost of the average sewer project is attributable to direct
labor (Sewer and Sewage Treatment Plant Construction Cost Index,
Table VI, p. 28);  and for the hypothetical waste treatment plant, the
labor cost component amounts to about 25.3% (p. 12).  From the region
of highest labor wage rate to that of lowest wage rate, there is

-------
                                             TABLE 18
                              Normal Plant Size Related to Relative
                                       Regional Unit Costs
Regions, Ranked in
Order of Ascending
    Unit Cost
 1  Southwest
 2  Gulf
 3  Pacific Coast
 4  Southeast
 5  Middle Atlantic
 6  Plains
 7  North Atlantic
 8  Ohio-Tennessee
 9  Great Lakes
10  New England
Median Design Size
Percent of Plants
to Population Served
Multiple
1.0 -
1.0 -
1.8 -
1.8 -
1.6 -
1.4 -
1.4 -
1.4 -
1.6 -
2.0 -
1.2
1.2
2.0
2.0
1.8
1.6
1.6
1.6
1.8
2.5
2.5 X Pop.
Requirement
14.3
6.2
38.5
36.3
31.9
15.2
26.5
22.0
24.3
41.3
4 X Pop.
Requirement
6.8
3.2
13.4
14.1
9.5
4.5
7.3
4.6
4.9
8.5

-------
a variation of some 50% in unit charges,  or enough to explain about
a nine to  twelve percent variation in final  costs, assuming equal
productivity in all parts of the nation.   Not only is the variation
in labor compensation rates of several orders of magnitude less than
the variation in unit costs, the relative ranking of high wage and
low wage regions has only a slight correlation with high and low
unit investment rankings, (cf. Table 19).  At any rate,  it is impossible
to ascribe to wage scale differentials the kinds of cost variation
that exist among the various parts of the nation unless  there are
also differences in labor productivity and labor application rates
far more profound than has been imagined.

     (5)   Climate and Geology.  One of the more likely  explanations of a
part of the cost differences centers upon the basic physical conditions
found in the several regions of the nation.  High unit costs cluster in
areas where severe winters reduce the effective period of construction.
Furthermore, grade and soil type may be expected to exert a heavy impact
on ultimate costs—certainly there can be no parity betv/een excavation
requirements in the flat, sandy soils of the Southwest and in the granite
hills of New England.

     (6)  Industry Diseconomies.  It is,  perhaps, not surprising, but
explanations for unfavorable relative cost position advanced from the
northeastern cluster of States have in no case included  engineering
or contractor deficiences.  Rigid administration, political corruption,
and union wage scales have all been indicated by engineers; but no one
has seen fit to suppose that unfavorable cost comparisons may trace to
the groups ultimately responsible for system design and  construction.
Yet design and overhead charges make up a significant portion of the
total cost of any project (cf. Table 20).  Moreover, sharp increases
in national allocation of resources to waste handling—in 1957, in
1961, in 1963, in 1967--have in every case resulted in a marked inflation
of project costs that most authorities agree to be traceable to con-
straints on the supply of engineering and construction services.
Professional qualification standards, trade groups, and  other mechanisms
intended to restrain supply—either for the purpose of controlling the
quality of services or v/ith the deliberate (if unstated) intent to re-
duce competitive market operations—may conceivably be regionalized to
a degree that costs are affected.
                                  45

-------
                                                                    TABLE 19

                                                  Wage Rates Related to Comparative Unit Costs
Region
Southwest
Gulf
Pacific Coast
Southeast
Middle Atlantic
Plains
North Atlantic
Ohio-Tennessee
Great Lakes
New England
Index, Total !/
Cost Per
Unit Reduction
43.1
58.1
68.8
72.2
81.9
102.6
132.9
141.1
159.3
455.2
City Measured
Denver
Dallas
New Orleans
Los Angeles
San Francisco
Seattle
Atlanta
Birmingham
Baltimore
Kansas City
St. Louis
New York
Pittsburgh
Philadelphia
Cincinnati
Cleveland
Chicago
Detroit
Minneapolis
Boston
Bldg.
Labor
.881
.674
.811
1.176
1.316
1.236
.751
.764
.868
.951
1.231
1.503
1.070
.997
1.101
1.321
1.166
1.238
1.075
1.075
Cstcn.
Labor
.868
.684
.718
1.195
1.336
1.255
.763
.776
.805
.968
1.250
1.526
1.055
1.000
1.087
1.303
1.184
1.258
1.105
1.013
Strctl .
Iron
Workers
.887
.807
.878
1.172
1.176
1.010
.885
.854
1.003
.857
1.000
1.362
1.016
1.087
1.031
1.123
1.122
1.157
.913
1.043
Elec-
trical
Workers
.879
.696
.830
1.067
1.228
.987
.906
.831
.889
.968
1.094
1.221
1.039
1.008
.943
1.050
1.034
1.077
.955
1.092
Steam-
Fitters
.909
.828
.865
1.209
1.453
1.026
.883
.878
.869
.919
1.138
1.170
.920
.994
.899
1.016
,981
1.081
,903
1.057
Power
Shovel
.767
.750
.864
1.139
1.220
1.093
.855
.758
.965
.838
1.005
1.362
1.035
1.109
.944
1.060
1.102
1.090
.963
1.055
Mean Wage *
Cost Index
(Rank)
.865 (3)
.784 (1)
1.183 (10)
.825 (2)
.899 (4)
1.018 (5)
1.137 (9)
1.073 (7)
1.078 (8)
1.056 (6)
y  Base Hourly Rate and Fringe Benefits for Indicated Classification as Reported In Engineering News Record, 2-29-68:
U
U.S. - 100
Subsidiary Indices/No, values Included
                                                          $3.86
$3.80
                                                                              $5.7$
fig N
 $5T
6
$6.16
$5.67

-------
                              TABLE  20

                 Major Components of Construction  Cost

                                  PERCENT OF TOTAL  COST

                                            Contractors     Overhead
                       Material     Labor       PI ant        and  Profit

Sewage Treatment  Plants   54.5       25.3        6.5            13.7
Sewers                    35.5       18.5       31.3            14.7

(Source:   Sewer and  Sewage Treatment Plant Construction Cost Index  p. 32)

     (7)   Urban Complexity.   Urbanization and consequent  concentration
of population  have been proposed as  explanations of  both  high  relative
regional  costs and low unit costs.   On  the one  hand, population  concen-
tration is presumed  to provide economies of  scale  that diminish  unit
investment needs.  On  the  other, it  has been asserted that  urbanization's
effect—in creating  transmission difficulties and  requiring higher
degrees of treatment—is to push unit costs  upward.

     There is  good logic on either side of the  argument;  but ranking
relative costs against relative urbanization suggests that  the actual
effect is neutral—see Table 21. One might conjecture that  the
arguments for  the effect of urbanization rest in large measure on mis-
apprehension.   The simplistic contrast  of vast  western areas of  small
population with the  mass of persons  concentrated along the  Atlantic
Coast and Great Lakes  gives a distorted view of the  nature  of  population
concentrations.  Constraints on development  imposed  by land forms and
water availability reduce  western utilization of land for urban  purposes
and make the effective rate of population concentration  in  the
western United States  much like that of the  Northeast and somewhat
more pronounced than that  of the South  and the  plains; so that the
actual effects of urbanization on waste handling costs are  probably
quite similar  through  the  Nation.

     Engineering  studies confirm without explaining  the  higher rela-
tive cost of Northeastern  sewage treatment plant construction.  Exami-
nation of specifications forwarded  in connection with applications  for
Federal grants produces—almost invariably—an  unfavorable  comparison
of estimated plant costs in New England, New York, and Pennsylvania
with similar facilities in other  parts  of the Nation. Sufficient
samples were not  available over the  last three  years to  provide  statis-
tically valid  cost  correlations for all waste treatment  processes on  a
regional  basis, but  enough examples  of  the most common waste treatment
method in the  Northeast—that is,  the activated sludge process—occur
to provide comparative construction  cost to  size statistics.  The
analysis (cf.  Table  22) revealed  a  sharply adverse cost  situation in
the area through  the range of sizes, with  costs becoming  progressively
less representative  as size of plant increased.

                                  47

-------
                                                   TABLE 21
00
       Regions, Ranked  1n
      Order  of Ascending
          Unit Cost
                                       Relative Urbanization Related to
                                        Unit Waste-Handling Investments
 Urban Population

Number       Percent
   Rank, Degree
of Urbanization
 Rural Population

Number       Percent
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
Southwest
Gulf
Pacific Coast
Southeast
Middle Atlantic
Plains
North Atlantic
Ohio-Tennessee
Great Lakes
New England
3
11
16
9
7
7
27
11
21
8
,757
,479
,937
,440
,318
,452
,810
,053
,436
,033
,000
,000,
,000
,000
,000
,000
,000
,000
,000
,000
72.
67.
80.
56.
57.
57.
81.
60.
71.
76.
5
7
6
4
1
4
4
8
6
4
4
6
2
10
9
8
1
7
5
3
1
5
4
7
5
5
6
7
8
2
,426
,474
,072
,284
,504
,534
,361
,121
,501
,478
,000
,000
,000
,000
,000
,000
,000
,000
,000
,000
27.5
32.3
19.4
43.6
42.9
42.6
18.6
39.2
28.4
23.6

-------
                              TABLE 22

                     Relative Construction Costs of
                       an Activated Sludge Plant

                                                          Mortheast
  Million            Investment Per  Million Gals/Day           as  a
 Gals/Day            	Capacity ($1957-59)            Percent of
 Capacity         Northeast*U.  S.  (Including Northeast)   U.  S.

     0.5          $893,000                 $516,000                173
     1.0           758.000                 404,000                188
     2.5           611,000                 286,000                214
     5.0           519,000                 229,000                227
    10.0           441,000                 179,000                246

* Six New  England States,  Pennsylvania,  New York.

     Whatever the reasons, the high capital cost of  waste  handling  in
the Northeast would seem to be documented adequately enough  to  be
accepted as  a fact.  And the  fact  that real costs  are significantly
higher in  the Northeast has serious implications for Federal  policy.
Quite apart  from the obvious  questions of equity and efficiency,  major
allocational  problems are  inherent  in  the particular composition
of regional  cost differences  that  exist in  the nation.

     (1)   Investment needs are strongly concentrated in the  Northeast.
The six New  England States, New  York and Pennsylvania contain just  over
20% of the Nation's population but  52°' of the sewered population that is
not provided with waste treatnent  services.   Moreover,  the region's
per-capita investment in waste handling facilities has--at least in
recent years--been well below that of  the rest of  the nation.

     (2)   Although the normalized  rate of annual  depreciation accruals
is lower on  a per-capita basis  than in other  parts of the nation, as  a
result of  the region's deficient capital base, many of the physical
facilities found in the Northeast  are  quite old and command a high
effective  rate of recapitalization. This,  together with a relatively
low rate of capital formation in the  area,  indicates that the Northeast
has been borrowing against its  real replacement and growth requirements
in recent  years.

     (3)   The rate of local  investment in waste handling facilities is
strongly conditioned by the  level  of Federal  assistance.  The allocation
formula that has been used has not reflected the particular difficulties
of the Northeastern situation; and the failure of appropriated Federal
funds to meet promised authorizations  has effected a mechanism that has,
                                 49

-------
perhaps, made matters worse.  In Northeastern States, pollution abate-
ment programs have been conducted in keeping with d logic that would
have the community needing a work proceed to finance that facility and
to construct it  in anticipation of future Federal (and sometimes State)
assistance payments.  The process might have been successful had all
other  things been equal; but there is  a vast difference between the
ability of communities and of the nation to command funds in financial
markets.  As money has become progressively tighter over the past five
years, the ability of  local government to finance needed projects has
become weaker,  so that the pace of construction  has not kept up with
growth of demand.  As  a  result, the  Northeast—in spite of a declining
share  of  total  population—has  sustained a  constant share of the national
need for waste  handling  facilities,  even without adjustment for the high
prices that  prevail  in the area.

                                TABLE 23

                Investment and  Demand,  Northeastern States
                         (Millions  of Dollars)


 State                 "Needs"    Investment    "Needs"    "Needs"  Developed
                       1962*     1962-67        1968*         1962-67

 Connecticut           29.9        52.6        53.2            75.9
 Maine                  77.3        16.2        66.5             5.4
 Massachusetts        145.4        61.3       151.6            67.5
 New Hampshire         49.1         15.6        44.6            11.1
 New York             215.1        211.2       200.0           196.1
 Pennsylvania         239.5       144.6       262.5           167.6
 Rhode Island           6.0        13.1        16.6            23.7
 Vermont               28.9        16.9        29.6            17.6

 Northeast Total      791.2       515.9       824.6           549.3
 (Percent of National
     Total)             (26)        (19)        (26)            (19)

 *Based on national  average unit costs

     Although the use of average costs in modelling investment require-
 ments  may be an acceptable technique  for evaluating most of the nation,
 dimensions  of the Northeastern States' deviation from the mean in  the
 past suggest the need for adjustment.  The range of variation elsewhere
 is relatively slight, and the sample  structure on which costs were
 determined  is well  distributed.  It is entirely conceivable, for example,
 that use of mean costs overstates South Dakota's or Mississippi's
 needs, in effect shifting the accounting of investments that take place
 in Michigan or Tennessee.  But the shift involved is not believed  to
 be highly significant and—more important—to be such that offsetting
 effects  produce a reliable national total.
                                   50

-------
     The situation is otherwise for the highest cost States.   Not only
is the difference in investment that may be involved of potentially
radical  significance, but the inadequate sample of Northeastern plants
going into the calculation of mean costs suggests that total  costs may
be understated.

     Though an entirely reliable set of calculations is not attainable
until a complete set of regional cost coefficients is derived, a partial
adjustment to reflect the added burden of the Northeastern States is
possible.  The adjustment presented in Table 24 utilizes the relation-
ship between costs of an activated sludge plant in the Northeastern
States and in the United States as its base.  Sewered populations of
the eight Northeastern States, distributed by community size, were
divided by total sewered population to obtain the segment affected by
a particular cost relationship.  The decimal values obtained were
weighted by the indicated cost relationship for the particular size of
community, and the product applied to the value of the State's need,
as that value had been determined by the evaluation model.

                               TABLE 24

                     Adjusted Investment Needs
                     Eight Northeastern States

                              Millions of 1957-59 Dollars

State                      Unadjusted     Adjusted     Increase

Connecticut                    53.2          97.6        44.4
Maine                          66.5          97.1        30.6
Massachusetts                 151.6         254.9        103.3
New  Hampshire                  44.6          68.8        24.2
New  York                      200.0         374.4        174.4
Pennsylvania                  262.5         457.9        195.4
Rhode Island                   16.6          31.2        14.6
Vermont                        29.6          41.8        12.2

Total                         824.6         1423.7        599.1

     The  effect of  the  adjustment  is  to  increase the scale of  indicated
national  needs  by 599 million base year  dollars,  or 827  million  current
dollars—twenty-six percent.   For  the eight State  region concerned,
it amounts  to  a 73% escalation of  costs.   Even that amount falls well
short of  the dimensions of the  cost  increase that  might  be anticipated
on the  basis of unit investment  differences encountered  during the
1962-67  period.   The adjustment  method is  consistent with  the modelling
process,  however; so the technique may be considered valid.   While a
larger  incremental  investment may  actually be  necessary  in the North-
east, it  is possible that the  uncalculated amount may be accounted for
by the  inter-regional  displacements  known to  occur as a  consequence
                                   51

-------
of average cost modelling.  In any event, no better procedure of adjust-
ment has been suggested.   In consequence, the regional investment
increment presented  here  has been used  in scheduling analyses that follow.

                   Alternative Investment Schedules

     For the period  immediately  ahead it is possible to determine with
some precision, by application of the evaluation models, the investment
that will be required  on  a national  scale to obtain the level of treat-
ment of public wastes  that has been  determined to match in a general
fashion the requirements  initially associated with water quality stand-
ards.  We know the approximate rate  at  which investment requirements are
accumulating, and we know the amount of the current accumulation of
needs.  The matter,  then, resolves to a simple scheduling problem:  to
find the annual rate of investment that will sustain existing physical
capital, meet expansion requirements, offset inflation, and eliminate
the accumulation  of  investment requirements that currently exists.

     To simply project past rates of need accumulation would be the
simplest method of determining an acceptable rate of investment.  It
is  unlikely,  however,  that the bulge in rate of development of needs
caused  by  imposition of the secondary waste treatment standard will be
repeated.   For  that  reason, the  projection process might be expected
to  overstate  the  rate of development of investment needs to be antic-
ipated  during  the early 1970's.  *

     A  more reasonable projection procedure is thought to be one which
takes  into  account both the existing capital base and prevailing rates
of  demand  formation  for constituent  elements of the investment complex—
i.e. growth,  recapitalization, and the  backlog of accumulated
demands—under a  series of capital supply assumptions.
 *  For those who wish to review the general  dimensions of requirements
 under  such  a procedure,  the elements are:

 1)   base current needs,  in millions of 1957-59  dollars = 3201.1
 2)   incremental  needs associated with higher costs  in Northeastern
        States =599.1
 3)   Rate of development  of needs, 1962-68  =
                     (X + I)  - Y
                           Y              = R = 12.1%  oer year
4)   projected  rate  of inflation =3.5% per year
5)   current  construction  cost index = 138% of 1957-59  (Over  a five
     year period,  needs  would  amount to $11,031.3 current  dollars,
     indicating an annual  investment requirement of $2.2 billion.)
                                   52

-------
     To effectuate the procedure, a computer program was developed to
apply varying amount of capital against combinations of demand constit-
uents.  The program assumed a constant 3.5% rate of inflation, and a
constant 3.3% rate of growth.  Recapitalization, capital in place, and
backlog were derivatives of investment.  The program dealt with recap-
italization as a prime element that had no effect on other elements of
the model.   (The condition in which total outlays failed to match
recapitalization requirements was not programmed.)  Growth needs were
calculated  to amount in any year to 3.3% of capital in place, and were
allotted the second segment of a postulated investment:  to the extent
that the investment covered growth requirements, the value was trans-
ferred to capital in place to serve as an element to calculate the
following year's recapitalization requirement, and values exceeding
available investment were accumulated as additions to the backlog of
unmet needs.  The backlog itself was reduced by any amount that avail-
able investment exceeded recapitalization and growth elements, or
increased as prior demands on a hypothesized investment exceeded the
amount of the investment.

     Repetitions of the exercise, applying a schedule of investments
increasing  in $100 million increments from $1 billion to $2 billion a
year, indicated that a $2 billion annual outlay is required to reduce
accumulated needs within a five year period,  (cf. Table 25A). Lesser
outlays, of course, increase the time required to attain control con-
ditions that approximate current interpretations of water quality
standards requirements.  Investments of less than $1.5 billion a year
not only postpone attainment, they are insufficient to keep pace with
the requirements of recapitalization, growth, and inflation, so that,
after an interim period of reduction, the backlog increases rather
than declines,  (cf. Tables 25B and 25C).

                               TASLE 25
              A-Five Year Backlog Elimination Schedule,
                   Water Quality Standards-Related
                         Public  Investments
               (Values in Millions of Current Dollars)

Year   "Backlog" at      Growth      Recapitalization   Investment
        year end
1969    4438.4
1970    3441.8            437.2              410.9          2,000
1971    2489.5            467.4              459.9          2,000
1972    1584.5            499.7              503.1          2,000
1973     730.0            534.3              555.7          2,000
1974      0               571.2              602.5          1,929.3
1975                      610.7              648.4          1.259.1

Total Indicated Investment,  1970-1974:                      9929.3*
     "Backlog"                                              4882.3
     Growth                                                 2509.8
     Recapitalization                                       2537.1
     *Includes an  Inflation  Component  of:   928.8

                                  53

-------
                         TABLE 25 Continued
                *B-Stretchout Schedule, Water Quality
                 Standards Related Public Investments
               (Values in Millions of Current Dollars)
         "Backlog" at
Year       year end

1969        4438.4
1970        3741.8
1971        3091.0
1972        2489.0
1973        1939.0
1974        1444.3
1975        1008.5
1976         635.3
1977         328.9
1978          93.4
1979           0
Growth
 437.
 467.
 499.
 534.
 571.
 610.
 653.0
 698.1
 746.4
 798.0
,2
,4
,7
,3
.2
,7
       Recapitalization
410.9
450.8
490.1
528.6
566
602
638
673
706
,2
,9
,6
,2
,6
             738.8
              Investment
1700.0
1700.0
1700.0
1700.0
1700.0
1700.0
1700.0
1700.0
1700.0
1630.2
                *C-Deficiency Schedule, Water Quality
                 Standards Related Public Investments
                (Values in Millions of Current Dollars)
         "Backlog" at
Year       year end       Growth

1969        4438.4
1970        4041.8         437.2
1971        3692.5         467.4
1972        3393.5         499.7
1973        3148.0         534.3
1974        2959.3         571.2
1975        2831.0         610.7
1976        2767.0         653.0
1977        2847.9         698.1
           Recapitalization
                  410.9
                  441.8
                  472.0
                  501.4
                  529.9
                  557.4
                  583.9
                  609.2
                           Investment
                             1400.0
                             1400.0
                             1400.0
                             1400.0
                             1400.0
                             1400.0
                             1400.0
                             1400.0
*Note:  Due to the inescapable pressures of growth and recapitaliza-
tion the investment results achieved with $2 billion a year in  five
years can only be attained in ten years with a reduction in spending
to $1.7 billion a year and at that level no decrease in investment
pressure is experienced; indeed by 1981, demand again reaches  the
$1.7 billion a year level and a backlog begins to accumulate by 1982.
At a level of $1.5 billion a year or less, the backlog is never elim-
inated.
                                 54

-------
     Within the terms of the analysis—which approximates reality,  in
that any failure to maintain physical  caoital  or to meet new demand will
inescapably add to the accumulation of unmet requirements—a critical
relationship may be found between the current level of investment,  $500
to $900 million a year, and the rate of formation of requirements under
the pressures of growth and recapitalization.

     We are already beginning to borrow heavily against the future
when we install new plants today.  The immediate effects are probably
not too serious, given the age composition of plants in place, most of
which were built fairly recently,  (cf. Table 26, that lists by periods
the approximate date of most recent major improvement or of initial
operation of all known municipal waste treatment plants.  Of those for
which information is available, over seventy-five percent were construct-
ed or reworked within the last ten years, more than eighty-eight percent
within the last fifteen years.)  But with each passing year, the poten-
tial seriousness of the current under-capitalization of public waste
handling becomes greater.  Twenty percent of the sewered population
of the United States is now served by over-loaded plants, and another
twenty-six percent of the sewered population is served by plants that
need major upgrading.

     A point must be made here.  There is nothing precise about any of
the numbers relating to investment.  They are presented to the nearest
hundred thousand dollars only to preserve mathematical integrity, not
because they are felt to quantify reality with the exactness that such
a  level of detail might be thought to imply.  The evaluations presented
in this report are to b_e viewed only as_ order of_ magnitude extrapolatjons
of existing conditions.  There are opportunities to reduce the weight
of the burden by enlightened planning and administrative policies.
Though technological innovations may be expected to have slight, if any,
impact on costs over so short a planning horizon as five years, the
existing technology does offer capital-saving expedients.   If the design
and construction industry of the northeast could reduce  its costs to
national average levels, well over half a billion dollars might be
saved within the projection period.  If the rate of inflation could be
rolled back to that obtaining in the first half of  the  last decade,
another three quarters of a billion dollars might  be  saved within the
period.  Use of more dependable  sizing techniques,  optimal  design
engineering, and more  intensive  application of regional  concepts might
all save hundreds of millions of dollars.  Conversely,  if  inflation
accelerates, design standards become more rigid, and  local  jealousies
intensify, the nation  can expect an even  larger  bill  to  be delivered.

     Comparison of  the  investment  schedules  indicates the  powerful
influence of time.  Not  needs  as such, but  the  rate at  which  needs
develop and are met becomes  the prime  question  in  evaluating  national
progress in providing  facilities to control water  pollution.  The
point  is as true for each State as  for the  United  States.
                                   55

-------
                                                  TABLE  26

                                       1968 Municipal  Waste  Inventory
            Summary of Haste Treatment Facilities  by  Year Plant  Underwent Major Revision (or Began)

State
Alabama
Alaska
Arizona
Arkansas
California
Colorado
Connecticut
Delaware
District of Columbia
Florida
Georgia
Hawai 1
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Maine
Maryland
Massachusetts
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
New Hampshire
New Jersey
New Mexico
New York
North Carolina
North Dakota
Ohio
Oklahoma
Oregon
Pennsylvania
Puerto Rico
Rhode Island
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Utah
Vermont
Virginia
Virgin Islands
Washington
West Virginia
Wisconsin
Wyoming
Date
Unknown
95
7
35
28
541
30
17
4
0
420
31
2
25
79
75
37
23
56
85
8
4
68
79
224
40
289
6
15
8
10
184
27
47
96
5
92
168
3
480
74
3
123
14
79
628
12
4
44
0
208
29
26
25
1900 and
prior
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
1
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
1901-
1910
0
0
0
0
0
0
1
0
0
0
0
0
0
1
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
3
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
1911-
1920
0
0
0
0
0
1
1
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
1
19
1
0
0
0
2
0
1
0
0
0
3
0
0
0
1
0
11
0
4
1
0
2
0
0
0
0
1
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
1921-
1930
2
0
0
0
0
0
3
0
0
0
0
0
0
7
2
20
6
1
1
0
0
0
4
0
0
0
1
6
0
0
12
0
21
1
3
3
0
2
0
0
0
0
4
0
0
0
0
7
0
0
0
0
0
1931-
1940
5
0
0
0
0
5
13
0
0
1
21
0
2
30
7
32
25
4
0
1
9
0
10
0
0
1
2
26
2
0
5
0
79
9
5
26
0
5
0
0
0
0
9
0
0
1
0
7
0
0
7
40
0
1941-
1950
4
0
0
0
0
5
9
0
0
1
17
0
1
35
10
27
38
5
0
0
3
1
5
0
2
0
8
20
3
0
3
0
20
5
16
13
0
n
0
0
i
0
16
1
0
4
0
12
0
0
3
46
0
1951-
1957
2
0
4
2
1
25
10
0
0
1
34
0
12
64
47
62
107
21
3
1
6
1
20
0
13
9
25
44
3
0
14
4
55
20
52
99
2
31
0
0
4
18
35
12
2
9
1
27
0
0
0
95
5
1958-
1962
33
0
8
57
4
48
14
3
0
31
36
5
22
167
66
109
116
34
35
6
17
9
51
55
61
96
45
93
2
7
24
16
99
58
86
134
86
47
1
6
2
31
56
46
105
12
12
65
0
0
25
103
30
1963-
1968
63
0
22
116
0
90
15
11
1
55
168
14
31
246
94
193
119
118
49
17
49
15
98
132
99
95
35
180
11
10
74
33
172
160
40
169
114
66
6
11
6
52
55
62
176
26
21
91
0
0
54
130
18

Totals
204
7
69
203
546
204
83
18
1
509
307
21
93
629
302
499
435
239
173
33
90
94
268
411
215
490
125
384
29
27
318
80
507
349
211
537
370
167
487
91
16
224
190
200
911
64
38
253
0
208
118
440
78
U.S. Totals
4,712
49
106
389
345   1,002   2,274    3,682   12,565
                                                     56

-------
Equally significant is the intention of the potential  investor—how
does the community rate pollution control  in its ranking  of all  needs
for funds?  How does the pressure of State programs express itself at
the local level?  What is the variance of  local  practice  from National
average standards?  All of these questions will  affect the distribution
of investment effort.   To provide a broad  estimate of  the magnitude of
investment facing individual  States if indicated treatment standards
are to be met, the scheduling process has  been applied.   Recognizing
that variations in design practice, growth rates, and  effective
recapitalization rates may be distorted by the application of nationally
derived coefficients,  decision-makers at the  State level may neverthe-
less find the values useful in formulating financial plans in the
field of water pollution control.

     Because the reliability of the assessment of investment
requirements declines  with the size of the element evaluated (a single
atypical project will  have a more pronounced effect on results for a
smaller than for a larger element), five year requirements for States
are presented in terms of a range—one standard deviation about the
mean—rather than an expected value.  The  principal variable affecting
the breadth of the range is plant size, so it would be unwise to infer
that a State's ultimate investment need will be to the low or high side
of the range on the basis of the generalized influence of location
on cost discussed earlier in this paper.  Rather, five year investment
requirements would be expected to occupy a mid-point in the range,
deviating to one side or the other according to the size of particular
projects that must be scheduled within the period.

     A similar problem of disaggregation is responsible for use of
five year lump sums rather than annual schedules.  Where the total
system of the nation might be expected to  sustain a constant annual
rate of investment under any given level of funding, subsystems may
be expected to demonstrate a certain lumpiness in allocation, according
to scheduling of particular projects.  (An exception to the rule might
be anticipated in the case of the six to ten most populous States.)
The exigencies of scheduling will, of course, affect gross investment
over the period, due to the varying effects of inflation, replacement,
and growth factors under different sets of time  conditions.

     These projections of investment levels are  considered to be
compatible with existing definitions of requirements, current unit
costs, a moderating inflationary influence, a five year  time period,
and a situation in which financial or resource  constraints permit
achievement.  A number of other  estimates  for the  individual States
exist,  and these may  be very different in  their details  than those
presented in  this report.

     Most of  the States have compiled  lists of  needed works.  In
particular, the FWPCA  requires  that  such  a  list  be a  part  of the
description of the State program in  submission  of  applications  for
                                  57

-------
program  grants.   Such independent estimates  differ  from the values
assessed here  in that they are situation-dependent  and time-independent.
Nevertheless,  they have tremendous value and pertinence, in that they
are  compiled by  men on the scene and represent  the  influence of both
subjective  and objective local factors.   In  particular, such estimates
may  be considered to provide surveys of  intention.  They represent an
evaluation  of  State and local  planning response to  conditions.

      Recognizing those values, one must  nevertheless approach at
least some  such  estimates with reservations. In some cases they must
be interpreted to be saying either 'this is  what we should like to
do in the absence of any constraints,1 or the direct opposite -- 'this
is all we think  we can do, given existing constraints.1  In distinc-
tion, the assessment provided in this report says substantially that
 'if we are  to  achieve presently defined  national  goals in a five year
time span,  the conditions that exist today indicate that we must
invest about  $2  billion a year.1  Unlike the other  evaluations, the
one presented  here is stringently constrained by time and observed
conditions.  It  is not, however, adjusted for either local practice
or local intentions.  While it is felt to be the best possible asses-
sment of national circumstances, its local  relevance is less defensible.
Table 27 presents the model-derived five year investment range
applicable  to  each of the fifty States,  the  District of Columbia,
Guam, Puerto  Rico, and the Virgin Islands.   Each  of the fifty-four
values is contrasted with the most recent (to January 29, 1970)
estimate by a  relevant organ of State or other  government of the
value of the  projects that it anticipates can occur within its juris-
diction  over  the next five years.  While the two  sets of estimates
are  not  strictly comparable, in that there are  substantial variations
at either end  of the time frame in the case  of  a  number of State
estimates — some run through  1975, and  a few include stages of 1969
projects -- the  SI0.2 billion  summation  tends to  support very
strongly the validity of the $9.9 billion,  five year estimate devel-
oped in  this report.

       But while  the order of magnitude validity of  a $10 billion
program  would  seem well  documented on a  national  scale, there are
very  troublesome  differences on a State  by State  basis.  Only eighteen
States -- one  third of the total  -- fall  into the indicated range
on the basis of  their own  assessments of investment requirements.
Fully  half  of  the  States  have  provided estimates  that fall below the
low value in the  range.   These apparently low estimates are not for the
most  part considered  to  be inconsistent  with the  terns of the national
scheduling  procedure  for  four  reasons:   1) The  modelling procedures
are intended to cover statistically probable value  of projects that
in many  cases will  not reasonably be foreseen at  the tirce^of a particular
survey, but  that will,  in  a  world that behaves  normally, occur within
the period.   2)  The  lumpiness  factor in  investment may push a major
                                  58

-------
                                                     TA^LE 27

                       Comparison of State Investment Intentions and Derived Value of Needs
                                               (Millions of Dollars)
                         State Intentions
                 Programmed
                   Needs
                  Intentions  Fall
                   Within Rantie
                                 Intentions
                                Exceed  Range
                                   Intentions
                                   Below  Range
Alabama
Alaska
Arizona
Arkansas
California
Colorado
Connecticut
Delaware
District of Columbia
Florida
Georgia
Hawaii
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Maine
Maryland
Massachusetts
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
Mew Hampshire
New Jersey
New Mexico
New York
North  Carolina
North  Dakota
Ohio
Oklahoma
Oregon
Pennsylvania
Rhode  Island
South  Carolina
South  Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Utah
Vermont
Virginia
Washington
West  Virginia
Wisconsin
Wyoming
Guam
 Puerto R1co
 Virgin Islands

        TOTAL
  35.0
  12.0
  86.0
  33.0
 651
 133.0
 280.5
  28.0
 355.0
 200.0
 150.0
  14.4
   0.5
 437.
 152.6
  33.3
  61. n
  62.6
 140.0
 140.9
 236.9
 438.0
 253.7
 136.3
  40.0
 390.0
  13.5
  62.0
  28.6
 138.0
 880.0
    9.9
 1900.1
  69.3
  22.0
 432.5
  65.3
 135.0
 432.0
  51.5
  75.0
  27.0
 105.5
 525.0
   11.7
   70.0
 151.0
 160.0
   44
  243.7
   12.0
    6.2
   28.9
   15.4

10217.1
 224.3
  12.2
  46.1
 118.6
 838.5
 143
 187
  17
  68
 209
 250
  44
  75
 493
 165.5
   7.6
  35.1
  72.6
 738.1
 103.
 147.
  12.
  19.
 157.
 198.3
  32.4
  58.1
 396.9
 337.6 - 282.8
 160,
 250.
 102.
 206.
 206,
  63,
 586.
 311.
 193.
 141
 359.1 -
 122
 118
  54.4
 104.1
 114.2
  29
 356
 249
 114
  82
 195
  63.7 -  42.1
 119.0 -
  38.6 -
 150.4 -
 343.4 -
  50.1 -
1323.6 -
 254.5 -
  38.9 -
 511.8 -
 123.0 -
 146.1 -
1122.8 -
  96.7 -
 121.8 -
  48.2 -
 184.9 -
  502.9
   82.4
  117.5
  152.8
  198.5
  140.3
  275.0
   38.3
  88
  30
  93
  262
  38
  788
  199.1
  31.9
  429.8
  94.0
  114.5
  720.8
  72.9
  96
  39
  115
  441
   68
  83
- 117.4
  146,
  101,
  231,
   19.1
   61.3 -  36,1
    4.4 -   2.6

11960.9-8473.7
X
X (a)

X (a)
X
                      39.9
> 10.3
                    >173.2




                    > 30.9




                    >536.6

                    >576.5
                                            >  22.1
                                       6.2

                                      11.0
                                                                                                         >130.5
                                     >. 39.6
                                     > 86.3
                                     ^48.3
                                     i 18.0
                                     £ 57.6

                                     ^130.2
                                     i 89.0
                                     I 57.3
                 i 42.2

                 i 28.6
                 E 26.4
                 >  1.4
                 >, 28.8

                 >129.8
                 i  9.9

                 ^28.7

                 i288.8
                 E 21.4
                 ^21.0
                 i 12.2
                 L 10.2

                 >.56.9
                 > 13.9
                                      L 56-8

                                      i  7.1

                                      >  7.2
 (a) Programmed  needs adjusted for  recent accelerated  level  of starts or state  intentions, excluding year 1975,
     bring two sets of estimates  into  agreement.
                                                        59

-------
project or projects that are normalized by the statistical method
wholly into or out of the  five year  time frame — as in the case
of the District of Columbia, where 80% of announced spending is scheduled
for 1975.  3)  The modelling procedure depends on uniform application
of high cost methods.   The choice of the high cost method was deliberate,
intended  to account for the observed tendency of real costs to increase
as conditions make it progressively  more necessary to orovide waste
treatment efficiencies  at  the extreme end of the scale for secondary
treatment processes.  Those States whose intentions to invest fall
below the low value in  the range tend to be the more economically
efficient in their conduct of the waste-handling activity, and to
employ lagoons  and other low unit cost methods.  The propensity of
real  costs  to rise —  and  in many cases, the simple fact of inflation --
are  not often taken  into account.  4) A final reason for variation
in estimates of State  liability  traces to an essential weakness in
the  estimating  model.   A uniform rate of loading growth has been
applied for every State, but States  do not grow at equal rates.
Unfortunately,  the components of growth are so randomly distributed --
 rate of population  increase,  rate of connection of water using industries,
 infiltration, and urbanization  all  bear on the matter — that it
 has  not proved   possible at this time to derive appropriate rates
 of growth for each   State.  Unquestionably, however, the effect of
 the modelling  procedure is to  create interstate transfers of growth.
 (Investment staging,  or lumpiness,  has  a bearing in  this regard.
 States with a good  deal of newly installed excess capacity will exper-
 ience growth of service that  does not necessarily require an investment
within the  five year time frame.)

       Some  of the same factors  explain higher  than  anticipated invest-
ment intentions.   Lumpiness in  investment  allocation is a reasonable
 explanation of  the  relationship of the two sets of  values in the
 cases of  Missouri,  Delaware,  Guam,  Texas  and  the Virgin Islands;  and
 in the case of  Arizona, both  lumpiness and  rapid growth come into
 play.  In a sense,  these jurisdictions expect  to begin  at an early
stage projects  whose  utility will extend well  into  the  future.  These
are,  then,  exoectable offsets  to some of the  States  whose intentions
fall  below  the  normalized range established  by the  model.

       Nine  States,  however, do  not  fall  within an explainable  range
of variability.   On  the low side, Alabama,  Hawaii,  Idaho, New  Mexico,
Pennsylvania, and West Virginia report intentions so far  below the
statistically probable that the difference  between  statistical proba-
bility and  pragmatic  observation, the lumpiness  factor,  the difference
between costs derived  from regional  practice  and normal  application
of the high  cost  method, or the effects  of varying  growth patterns
provide no  explanation.  Equally difficult  is  the high  divergence of
expressed intentions  from the  normal range  in  the cases of  New Jersey,
                                  60

-------
                                         INVESTMENT INTENTIONS
                                      COMPARED TO DERIVED NEEDS
n
                      INEXPLAINABLY LOW, 6 STATES
                 'EXPECTABLY" LOW, 21 STATES
                       EXPLAINABLY HIGH, 6 STATES
              INEXPLAINABLY HIGH, 3 STATES
              WITHIN RANGE OF ESTIMATE, 18 STATES
                            Figure 3

-------
New York, and Maryland.   (The latter may to some extent reflect
double counting with the  District of Columbia for projects in the
Washington, D. C. metropolitan area.)

      One can only  conjecture that reporting discrepancies or
specialized influences make  some aspects of the States' situations
abnormal.  At any rate, in comparing the values, the reader may obtain
some grasp of the plasticity of the situation, the extraordinary
variety  of conclusions that  may be reached where the rules of the
game are largely unspecified.

     The rules of the game,  as it is ultimately to be played, are
all  important.  There are sizeable dimensions of uncertainty relating
to  plant scale, regional  cost differences and timing of investment.
Actual  treatment needs  to meet water quality standards may vary markedly
in  many situations  from  preliminary assumptions because of local con-
ditions.  Changes  in  the  rate of  industrial connections to municipal
plants, improvements  in  technology, greater use of regional treatment
facilities will  all have  an  impact on  actual costs, and these can only
be accommodated  by  the  analytical method with a set of projection
assumptions  that may finally prove to  diverge in several  respects from
 the eventuation of conditions.   Perversely, even Federal  policy and
 legislation  based  on  a  level of  need will tend to make any estimate
 self-fulfilling  by imposing  external  stimuli on local  decision making.

                   A Compatible  Industrial Schedule

      Because the same elements  apply  to the  industrial sector—i.e.
 investment rates  represent the  interaction of technological requirements,
 capitalization,  growth,  replacement,  and price  levels  over time—the
 same scheduling  techniques may  be utilized to determine  investment norms
 for manufacturers.

      We have a fairly good grasp of  the dimensions of those elements  in
terms  of the definitions presented  in  the first report of this series.
 It is  recognized  that there are  significant  weaknesses in that assess-
ment,  weaknesses  that derive principally from data  deficiencies.
Because no significant new information has  come to  light in the  two
years  since  the  issuance of that report (and because such information
as industrial  sources have provided  tends  to corroborate the  values
 reported), no attempt has been  made  to refine the estimates presented.
In the absence of information that might alter  the  earlier estimates
in some substantive fashion, they have been  fitted  into  the scheduling
equation.

      Because the input variables were originally presented as a  range
 (whose bounds may  be thought to  represent technological  possibilities
frontiers) a mid-point value is  used to present the results of the
scheduling effort  in Table 28.   The  elements of the table include  1)
the mid-point investment requirement increased  by two years'  estimated


                                  62

-------
                               TABLE  28

                             Water Quality
             Standards-Related  Manufacturers'  Investment
                         For Waste Treatment
                (Values  in  Millions of Current Dollars)

Year     "Backlog"  at        Growth      Recapitalization     Investment
	      Year End              	      	     	

1969       1513.2
1970       1129.5              139.4           118.5           650.7
1971        817.3              150.8           138.0           650.7
1972        526.4              163.1           156.9           650.7
1973        258.0              176.4           175.2           650.7
1974         —                190.8           192.8           650.7
1975         --                206.3           209.7           416.0

Total indicated Investment  *               =  3253.5
       "Backlog"                             1651.6
        Growth                                820.5
        Replacement                           781.4
        * Includes  an Inflation Component of   330.0
                                 63

-------
normal growth  and  recapitalization  requirements  and  decreased by reported
1968 investment  and  projected  1969  investment; 2)  annual growth assessed
at 4.5%;  3)  annual  recapitalization assessed  at  4%;  4)  annual inflation
assessed  at  3.5%.  The dynamics  of  industrial waste  treatment are
considered to  include  significantly higher  growth  and recapitalization
functions than is  true of municipal v/aste treatment, so that industrial
investment requirements are  climbing faster than are municipal.   This
traces to the  fact that the  major part of the public investment is for
transmission facilities that are replaced at  a slower rate than waste
treatment plants,  and  that industrial production is  increasing at
distinctly more  pronounced rates than population.

     Given the data  set and  the  assumptions that underlie it, the
situation that emerges is one  in which manufacturing industries must
invest about $650  million a  year over the next five years to achieve an
equilibrium  level  of capitalization, one in which  investments are re-
quired only  to meet  the exigencies  of annual  recapitalization and
growth.   The current level of  investment appears to  be  comfortingly
close to  the target  amount.  Unless some significant changes in the
rules of  the game  become necessary, industrial facilities may be
expected  to  come on  stream according to the hypothetical schedule
that  reflects  current  national policy.

      Water  Pollution  Control  Needs at Federal Installations

      In  order to  correct existing  water pollution control needs at
Federal installations, an estimated $246.5  million dollars will be
required.  Sources of  information from which  this  cost  is derived
include Bureau of  the  Budget Circular A-81  and a recent questionnaire
from the  Bureau  of the Budget  to Federal Agencies  entitled "Status of
Water Pollution  Projects at  Federal Facilities-FY  1968-1970."

      Circular A-81  is a budget  process developed  in 1967 for the
purpose of a phased  and orderly  plan to correct  water pollution
problems  that  exist  at Federal installations.  Its original intent did
not cover estimated  treatment  facilities for  new construction or
expected future  needs  at existing facilities.  Each  agency submits
to the Bureau  of the Budget  an estimate of  cost  for  each installation
where proposed treatment facilities are tentatively  scheduled for a
given annual budget.   Also included in the  submission are summaries,
programming  all  projects planned by each agency  by fiscal year.
FWPCA has assumed  that estimates do not include  cost escalation factors
for projects in  fiscal  years other  than the one  reported on.  Each
year FWPCA is  called upon by the Bureau of  the Budget for advice and
recommendations  as to  the seriousness of the  proposed projects.  From
the time estimates of  cost are prepared by  the agency to the time of
submission of the  annual  budget  to  Congress,  cost  figures sometime
change considerably.   The Agency's  experience is that revisions are
invariably upward.    Final  cost figures are  not usually made available
to FWPCA,  therefore any  representation of these  costs made by FWPCA can
only be interpreted as  a  rough approximation.


                                  64

-------
     The status questionnaire asked for information in regard to
pollution projects programmed and funded from FY 1968 through FY 1970.
In FY 1968 and FY 1969 a total of $108.8 million was programmed of
which $76.3 million has been appropriated creating a deficit of
$32.5 million.  In addition when the questionnaire was compared v/ith
Circular A-81  submissions for the same years, it was also discovered
that some projects were not included.  These omissions further qualify
the reliability of the $246.5 million dollars.   What is available,
then, is no more than a tentative schedule of appropriation requests
over a ten year period. The proposed schedule as originally programmed
was:

           Fiscal Year *              Estimated Expenditure

          1968-1969                   $   32,500.0

          1970                            47,500.0

          1971                            43,000.0

          1972                            97,000.0

          1973-1978                       26,500.0
          Totals                      $  246,500.0

*  Originally programmed but not yet funded.
                                  65

-------
                         FEDERAL  COST-SHARING

       Nature of Grant Programs and the Reasons  for Cost-Sharing
       To properly evaluate Federal  cost-sharing  it is  necessary to
trace the recent history of how cost-sharing  developed, and  to
define the concept with respect to the Federal  Water Pollution
Control Act.

       Intergovernmental fiscal relations  have  increased since the
1930's.  There are several  reasons for this  increased activity.
Increased urbanization and  a faster pace of  economic growth  have
created more  demands for services provided by local governments.
While the demands have been felt at the local level, the availability
of increased  revenues has been at the State  and particularly at the
Federal level.  Through fiscal participation an equilibrium  of supply
and demand for public funds can be obtained  often.   This amounts to
a direct pass-through of Federal  funds to  strapped  local coffers.

      Another reason for the growth of payments from Federal to
State and local governments has been the desire of  groups to
influence both the level and nature of public expenditures.   The
rationale for these intergovernmental expenditures  is that the
quality of activity of one  area will affect  outside areas.  Further-
more, the higher levels of  government will be better able to direct
a uniform performance as compared with local  governments working
toward their own particular ends.  Financial  participation serves
as an incentive to local governments and as  a means of adjusting
financial inequities that might develop.

      Another rationale for intergovernmental financial cooperation is
provision of relief to poorer regions and  to lower income levels.  The
justification for this financial aid rests upon the belief that this
can best be accomplished by larger rather  than  by smaller units of
government.  For if income  redistribution  were  accomplished on a local
basis, some communities would have a greater burden per capita than
others.  The justification  for this type of financial aid rests on the
given national objective concerning income equilization,, and on the
many benefits which do not accrue solely to the individuals in these
economic conditions but which accrue also to the nation.

      In light of these considerations Federal  financial architects
have designed numerous methods of cost-sharing.  Included among the
methods are: income equilization—allocating relatively more grants
                                  67

-------
to poor areas  than  to  prosperous  ones;  optimizing—using functional
cr categorical  grants  to  increase efficiency  in performing-specific
objectives;  and block  grants—passing  via  unconditional grants Fed-
eral ponies  to State and  local  governments.   For each alternative
thf  irpact of  fiscal Federalism varies.  What alternative or combin-
ation  of  alternatives  should  be chosen depends on the purpose of the
grant  and the  social welfare  function, the objectives of the decision
maker.

       To  establish  the nature and level  of P/JPCA cost-sharing programs,
the  objectives and  rationale  for the program  first must be considered.
Is the program a means of redistributing income and/or a means of
collecting and distributing  tax dollars?  Does the program have a
specific  optimizing function?  The basis for  distributing the grants,
allocation formulas, can  be  established only  after those questions
are  answered.

The  stated purpose  of  the construction grant  program is to prevent
untreated or inadequately treated sewage and  waste from being dis-
charged into water  (Federal Water Pollution Control Act as amended
Section 8a).  The desirability of the  grant is based on the propriety
of the Federal aid, the public necessity for  the work, the relation-
ship of total  system costs to benefits, the benefits received from
the  work, and  the ability to  maintain  physical capital (Section oc).
Judging from these  provisions in the Act,  it  appears that the grant
program is directed to accomplish a specific  objective, and may be
classified an  optimizing  grant.

                    Level  of  Federal  Hrant Support

     There are a number of persuasive  reasons why Federal financial
support for  State and  local pollution  abatement efforts may be con-
sidered to be  appropriate. Ultimately, these devolve upon two consid-
erations, equity and financial  necessity.

     The equity argument may be set forward very briefly.  It holds
that pollution  control  is  an  expression of a  national priority (which
may  often conflict  with local  priorities that would put industrial
development, lower  taxes,  or  alternative use  of public funds well
ahead of  pollution  control);  and  that  the  benefits of improved water
quality extend  in tire  and place  well  beyond  the point of the action
that results in  improvement,  so that they  are most often regional or
national  in  nature.  Thus  the  community should in equity bear the
cost of reducing  the damages  it creates, but  there is equal equity
in requiring that the  beneficiaries  of such actions —in essence,
the nation at large—bear  some  costs.   Cost-sharing between Federal
and local  governments,  then,  represents  a  rough and ready accommod-
ation to the principles of levying  charges against both the
occasioners  of damage and  the recipients of benefits.  The same
                                   68

-------
considerations of equity argue strongly for State participation in
costs, since State- government has a nore proximate relation to
than does Federal government, and more directly represents benefitted
population than does local government.

      The financial necessity argument extends f?r beyond the area
of pollution control.  It is directed to the f?ct that fiscal demands
on State and local governments are increasing faster than the growth
of their revenues—at least as these are derived from traditional
sources—or faster than gross national product.  Cut while State and
local governments face a responsibility to provide an increasing share
of the goods and services produced in the national economy, the
Federal governnent holds the most efficient taxing mechanisms in its
powers.  Further, the disparity between State and local means and
requirements is increased in practice by the fact that those services
provided by such governments are n;cst needed in precisely the places
where financial resources are most limited.  Under such conditions,
Federal financial assistance becomes a necessary precondition to the
conduct of the expanding program requirements of State and local
government.

     The situation has been too adequately analyzed and documented
elsewhere to require further discussion in this place,  (cf.
especially Revenue Sharing and Its Alternatives:  '-/hat Future for
Fiscal Federalism, Subcommittee on Fiscal Policy of the Joint
Economic Committee, °0th Congress, July 1G67, and Fiscal Balance in
the  American Federal System, Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental
Relations, Washington, P. C., October 1967).  The question is not
the  necessity of Federal financial assistance, but the amount of
such assistance that is required to achieve particular national goals.

      Some guidelines as to amount are offered in the form of studies
by specialists in governmental fiscal matters.  (Detailed citations
may  be found in sources cited above).  Joseph Pechman, Richard
Netzer, and Selma t'ushkin and Gabrielle Lupo have provided some very
generalized assessments of an appropriate overall mix of  Federal
and  local financial efforts, based on the fiscal  gap created by the
difference between the rate of growth of State and local  revenues
and  their outlays.  The estimates agree fairly closely, suggesting
the  need for a 17 percent to 21 percent Federal financial participa-
tion in local government programs by  1970.  The developing situation
is one in which expansion of local government services can only take
place with a substantial increase  in  the Federal  share of the cost
of such services.  (See Table 29).

      Significantly, Joseph Pechman's estimate of the  situation
assumes that financial constraints will cause a  reduction in the rate
of increase in production of State and  local  governmental services.
Where the other authorities assume that economic  growth,  new revenue
sources, and increased borrowing  can  sustain  growth of local govern-
ment services, Pechman projects  a  revenue  supply  that  has a  low

                                   69

-------
                               TABLE 29
              Estimates of State and Local  Governments
                 Needs for Federal Financial  Support
                        (Billions of Dollars)

                                                     Mushkin
                                   Pechman     Netzer   &Lupo

Demands on State & Local
 Governments, 1965                    74         74      74
Local Taxes & Borrowing               63         63      63
Federally Supplied                    11         11      11

Demands of State & Local
 Governments, 1970                   103        121      122
Local Taxes & Borrowing               80        100      100
1965 Level of Federal Support         11         11      11
Fiscal Gap                            12         10      11

Percent Federal Participation, 1965   15%        15%     15%

Percent if Gap is to be
 Federally Closed, 1970               21%        17%     18%

Indicated Federal Participation
 in Incremental Outlays               41%        21%     23%
                                  70

-------
elasticity, and a slowing in the growth of this sector of the economy
even with a relatively larger input to the Federal  share of total
revenue.  In view of the events of the past two years--when markets
for State and local bond issues have consistently failed to meet
needs, even at constantly increasing price levels,  and when taxpayer
revolt has stifled new revenue measures at the polls—the Pechman
view of the world seems to have been the more accurate one.

      At any rate, the sources seem to agree that we are in a
situation where continuation and extension of pollution control
efforts will require that of every five dollars expended by some
level of government, at least one dollar must come  from Federal
sources.  Given the fact that the national priority system probably
holds water pollution control somewhat higher in its ordinal rank-
ing than do at least those communities which have failed to provide
needed treatment works, a higher level of Federal financial assis-
tance may actually be required to achieve needed controls.

      At this time the Federal input to public waste handling
activities approximates the relative share projected by the autho-
rities on governmental finance who have been cited.  Currently, the
combination of grants through the Department of the Interior,
Housing and Urban Development, and Agriculture amounts to something
over a quarter of a billion dollars a year; while total State and
local spending for waste handling is estimated to exceed $1.4 billion
annually.  (See Table 30).  Federal spending in this area has in-
creased tremendously, both in absolute terms and relatively to the
outlays of local government.  Yet constraints upon local finances
have forced many States to provide supplemental assistance to local
government in the waste handling area.

      The reason is not difficult to determine.  Although Federal
outlays have increased at a much greater rate than those of local
government, the amount of the Federal increase has been well below
that which local government has had to meet.  Federal outlays for
capital investment purposes have been about $170 million greater
this year than they were in the first five years of the Federal waste
treatment construction grants program.  But total capital outlays
are almost $400 million a year higher, indicating a $230 million a
year incremental burden on local governments.  Indeed, annual
replacement costs for the systems constructed since initiation of
the grant program are estimated to have increased by about $235
million a year, which combined with about $105 million a year increase
in operating costs, means that one of the effects of the level and
nature of Federal assistance in the pollution control effort has been
to directly add a third of a billion dollars a year to the financial
burden of American local governments.

      The fact, taken in the context of the continuing financial
crisis of local government, does much to explain the very slow
                                  71

-------
                             TABLE 30

         Relation of Federal Assistance to Total  Estimated
                 Public Waste-Handling Expenditures
                       (Millions of Dollars)
Annual Average
Outlay for Period
    Investments           Operating  Charges
Treatment  Collection  Treatment  Collection
  Works       Works      Works       Works
Total
1956-61, Total
Federal Share
1962-66, Total
Federal Share
1967, Total
Federal Share
339
45
515
105
551
203
317
375
504
50
95
135
170
170
195
200
921
45
1210
105
1424
253
Percent Federal in
  Period

    1956-61             13
    1962-66             20
    1967                37
                10
   5
   9
  18
                                  72

-------
incremental reduction of pollution abatement needs in recent years.
Local government must spend as much today to hold its own in terms
of pollution abatement activities as it was spending to increase
those capabilities a few years ago.  Overhead expenditures for opera-
tion, maintenance, and replacement largely cancel the effects of
Federal grant assistance.  Larger Federal funding is necessary to
extend the reach of public waste handling and pollution abatement
capabilities.

      The appropriate level of funding over the short run depends
upon several factors, specifically, the degree of cost-sharing on
each project, the method of allocating funds among States and the
time period in which all untreated wastes from sewered communities
are to be treated and an upgrading and replacement posture is to be
reached.

      The impact of the degree of Federal participation must be
appraised.  The rate at which a stable investment posture is to be
attained is a function of the residual funds available after
existing facilities are expanded, maintained or replaced.  The
concept expressed here is that failure to adequately sustain exis-
ting capital automatically creates an investment need, and adds to
the national backlog.  Thus, the sooner it is desired to achieve a
zero "backlog" level the higher the amount of total and Federal
investment shares.  But the increase is by no means likely to be
greater than the marginal limits of expansion and contraction around
the historical level of investment. Accelerating construction too
steeply will tend to increase costs more than proportionately
through sectoral inflation caused by bottlenecks in design capacity,
construction industry capacity and equipment manufacturing capability.
In addition, significant changes in investment levels may conceiv-
ably drive up interest costs in the already high municipal bond
market.  Another impact may well be poorer quality works, in terms
of both design and construction, resulting from  less stringent
quality control and the attraction of engineers  and  contractors
with lesser skills in the waste treatment field.

       While a program is considered more effective  if  it  results  in
more pollution control in a shorter time than another, the time
shrinking may cause that program to be  less efficient.  The  tradeoff
between these two factors is difficult  to predict.

                        A Retrospective  View

       Whether viewed as  an urban development  program or as an  invest-
ment in natural resource protection,  the wave of .treatment systems
construction that has taken place  since  the end  of  the Korean war—
most of it with the assistance of  Federal  grants—has  profoundly
changed the  conditions  and the attitudes that characterize waste
handling  procedures in American  urban  areas.  And  it is those  changes,
                                  73

-------
the result of the program's operation, which have made the present
alignment of grants unsuitable for today's conditions.

      The dimensions of change are Illustrated 1n Figure 4.  In
1940 just before the United States entry into World War II, one
American 1n two was served by a sewer system and little better than
one 1n four—or about half of those connected to sewers—was served
by a waste treatment facility.  A decade later, the relationships
had scarcely changed.  The exigencies of war, of industrial restruc-
turing, of recovery from the after effects of the Great Depression,
had shaped a set of national priorities in which the complexities of
waste disposal were relegated to a low position.  The proportion
of the national population connected to sewers was still 53 percent—
just what 1t had been 1n 1940.  Waste treatment was provided to 60
percent of the sewered population, as compared to 53 percent in 1940;
but the gain was due in larger measure to accidents of location than
to new construction—cities with waste treatment tended to be in
relatively fast growing areas.

      But with the end of the Korean War and the eventual saturation
of the repressed demand for consumer goods that accumulated during
the long years of war and depression, the United States turned its
attention toward a number of broad public investments—highways,
education, urban renewal, and waste disposal among them—that began
to rework the face of the nation.  By 1957 when Federal grants for
construction of waste treatment works were initiated, 57 percent of
the total population was connected to sewers—20 million persons
more than in 1950—and more than three quarters of those sewered
were supplied with waste treatment, an addition of 28 million persons
1n seven years.  The great Increase in public works expenditures
involved In that expansion of facilities was probably the principal
source of the construction grants mechanism, which was initially
viewed as a financial assistance measure.  In the twelve years in
which such grants have been available, sewered population has
Increased by 37.5 million persons, and now amounts to almost seventy
percent of the population of the United States.  Population served
by waste treatment has increased by more than 51 million to account
for more than 92 percent of those presently served by sewers.  In
twenty-eight years the population of the United States increased by
about 65 million, the sewered population increased slightly more in
absolute numbers but far faster in relative terms—a 94 percent
Increase as opposed to a 48 percent Increase—and the population
served by waste treatment increased by more than 88 million or
almost 240 percent.  Of those totals, more than half of the Increase
In sewering and more than three-fifths of the Increase in application
of waste treatment have occurred since the Inauguration of Federal
waste treatment plant construction grants.

      The transformation in waste handling procedures has been
qualitative as well as quantitative.  Considerably more money has
                                  74

-------
             Figure 4
 GROWTH OF PUBLIC
   WASTE HANDLING
       SERVICES
 Unsewered Population
                    Secondary Treatment
1940
1950
1960
1968
               75

-------
been  spent to extend, expand, replace, and upgrade facilities  than
has been  spent for Initial Installation.  As a result we may presume
that  treatment facilities in operation 1n 1969 were more efficient
than  those 1n operation a decade before.

       We  know that there 1s a great deal more capacity  for expansion
In  today's plants, so that a good portion of population Increase
that  occurs in the future can be Included in currently  operating
systems for minimal additional Investment.  Perhaps most significant,
expansion of treatment capabilities has Induced a great change in
treatment procedures.  Where plants in place in 1940 and 1950  were
Intended  to treat sanitary wastes, current thinking dictates that In
most  cases the municipal waste treatment plant treats all  of the
wastes generated within the municipal jurisdiction, so  that public
waste handling services are far more comprehensive; and their  exten-
sion  has  been a major means of mediating the polluting  effects of
Industrial waste discharges, as these have been progressively  In-
corporated in municipal systems.

       Figure 5 which graphs public expenditures since 1952 for
liquid waste handling capital demonstrates fairly clearly  that
each  Increase In the level of Federal appropriations for waste
treatment plant construction grants has moved total public  spending
to  an Irregular, new plateau.  Particularly sharp peaks in  1963 and
1967  reflect the effects of complementary Federal assistance
programs, the Accelerated Public Works Program In 1963  and  Initiation
of  Department of Housing and Urban Development sewer grants in 1966-67,

       The overall shape of the expenditures line 1s not, however,
as  significant In mirroring the Impact of Federal financial assistance
as  1s the configuration of Us consitituents.  Investments  in  collec-
tion  sewers, which ascended at roughly the same slope as others types
of waste  handling capital expenditures prior to the Initiation of
the grants program, tended to flatten at the time that  the grant
provision (which does not Include collection sewers) was enacted.
Availability of Federal assistance, combined with a certain degree of
substitutablllty between collection sewers and other types of waste
handling  Investment,  acted to channel funds into the treatment plants
and ancillary works that do qualify for FWPCA grants.

      Just as  the emphasis on treatment-related Investments to the
relative disadvantage of collection facilities demonstrates the
ability of Federal  policy to Influence local decisions,  the rela-
tively minor Investments made for new treatment plants  Indicates the
ability of local  recipients to utilize Federal funds In ways that
relate to  local needs.   Less than a third of the total  monies  ex-
pended for purposes that qualify for the grant assistance has  been
used 1n the construction of new plants.   The less dramatic, but very
real, need  to equip,  expand, improve, automate,  and replace plants
                                   76

-------
                           Figure 5
1500
1350
1200
1050
900
o
o

"S
M
 750
600
 450
300
 150
                    PUBLIC  INVESTMENT  IN

                 WASTE-HANDLING SERVICES,

                          1952-1967
         Waste Transmission,  System Expansion,

              Replacement & Upgrading
 BIUII,  .

V
                    -
                      New Waste

                   Treatment Plants
             /v/    \  i
                           Collecting Sewers
                  Accelerated Public Worksi
           I  I   I
                             Fed'l Construction Grant Appropriations

                      I  I  •   '  '   '., i   i  i  i   i  i  i   i  i
          1952
                       1956
1960
                                         1965
                                                      1969
                           77

-------
has been  the  source of the principal  portion of local government's
demands on  the  grants  program.   Each  expansion  of Federal funding
has been  translated into an increase  in expenditures of the miscel-
laneous sorts required for system rationalization;  and the level
of new plant  expenditures for previously untreated  wastes has scarcely
changed over  more than a decade of experience.

      Federal intention and local need, then, have  interacted to
shape the instrument,  the Federal grant for construction of waste
treatment works.   Application of that instrument has taken forms
that neither  level of  government might have foreseen.

                            The Federal Share

     It is, of course, difficult to say just how much money the Federal
government  should provide to achieve  "adequate" waste treatment.  The
amount would  be a function of the cost-sharing  formula (assuming local
ability to  provide necessary matching funds) and of time.

     Economic theory provides no real insight into  some optimum level
of  Federal  funds, leaving the political process to  decide upon that
level which reflects national interests and values.  But economic
theory can  provide insights into the  potential  for  matching by State
and  local governments, the time to eliminate non-current unmet needs
and  the potential success in mustering necessary resources at various
dollar levels of Federal program.  The potential  inflationary impact
and  incentive effects  can also be evaluated for these alternative
levels.

      Ignoring for the noment inflationary side-effects and the more
difficult problem of incentives, let  us consider the matter of optimum
Federal participation  in financing facilities:   There is a pressing
need to elicit an average annual investment rising  from a current value
of about  a  billion dollars a year, plus a need  to eliminate a "backlog"
of about  $4.4 billion  worth of required works.   There is a definite re-
sistance  on the part of some of the local governments who must finance
this investment,  a resistance due to  expression of  local priorities and
to financial  constraints, concomitant with a very strong Federal in-
terest in maintaining  and increasing  the rate of investment.  All com-
ponents   of the investment deficiency are not of equal immediacy:  Some
facilities  needs  are quite pressing,  in terms of alleviating stresses on
the aquatic environment; some are little more than  administrative re-
quirements. It  must be recognized that each dollar  invested creates an
immediate charge  on local government  to expend  additional dollars to
operate and maintain the function created by the investment.  Finally—
and a most  significant consideration  in determining meaningful Federal
policies—the need will  never be fully met: its nature will change, its
geographic  distribution  will  shift, the means of dealing with it will
fluctuate;  but  human activities will  always create  wastes, and society
will always be  forced  to ameliorate the environmental stresses implicit
in waste  disposal.   The  task is a continuing social and technological


                                    78

-------
                TABLE  31
       Dollars of Total  Investment
Per Dollar of Federal  Construction  Grants

Year
1957
1958
1959
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
Total
Investment
11.54
13.40
13.24
13.78
9.54
8.92
10.04
8.62
6.40
6.13
5.20
Sewer
Investment
4.94
6.20
6.72
7.18
4.75
3.55
4.05
3.P6
2.74
2.66
2.49
                                   Treatment Plant
                                     Investment

                                        6.60

                                        7.20

                                        6.52

                                        6.60

                                        4.79

                                        5.37

                                        5.99

                                        4.66

                                        3.66

                                        3.47

                                        2.71
                   79

-------
Imperative,  and society can only redistribute financial stress over
time,  not  eliminate the task by any massive,  short  term investment
program.

     Of  importance in this decision too is the multiplier effect of
Federal  funds  which is shown historically in  Table  31.  The recent
history  shows  a decrease in the multiplier, which may be partially a
result of  increased cost sharing ratios beginning with the 1965 legis-
lation and the institution of HUD grants for  sewers  in 1966.

     Whatever  the level of Federal participation and the method of
allocation their impact will be felt at the State and local level.  The
effects  of an  illustrative program have been  examined for New England
and  they are presented in the following case  study.

                                CASE STUDY

       Financial  Impact of Constructing Hater Pollution Control
                        Facilities in New England

Introduction
      The purpose of this case study is to investigate and evaluate the
 financial  aspects, arrangements and impact of constructing water pol-
 lution control  facilities in New England.  For illustrative purposes
 only, it evaluates the financial impact a 50  percent Federal grants
 program might have on each of the New England States.  The major
 emphases on case study was to show the distribution of costs among
 the levels of government, and more specifically the burden on the
 municipal  sector.   For this purpose a hypothetical level of Federal
 funds was  selected.   The case study assumes that adequate Federal funds
 will  be forthcoming to provide a 50% Federal  investment in the "ew
 England States.   The state, local and Fedora1 shares predicated on this
 assumption are shown in Table 32.  Other aspects considered in the study
 are:   (1)  past sewerage expenditures relative to needs; (?) expenditures
 of  State and local governments for education, highways, public welfare,
 etc.; (3)  the fiscal capacity and tax effort  of State and local govern-
 ments; and (4)  alternative financial arrangements.

      The case study first considers the impact at the State level then
 the impact at the  community and homeowner levels.  Alternative means
 of  financing the program at the local community level are evaluated in
 Examples  I & II.

 Cost  of Water Pollution Control  Facilities

      The cost of providing treatment facilities and interception (exclu-
sive  of collection systems)  for municipal  and some industrial wastes in
New England  is estimated to be approximately  $1.12 billion for the next

-------
                                     TABLE 32
                  FEDERAL, STATE AND LOCAL SHARE OF FINANCING
             THE COST OF WATER POLLUTION CONTROL FACILITIES IN NEW ENGLAND
State
Connecticut
  Total Cost
  Federal
  State
  Local*

Massachusetts
  Total
  Federal
  State
  Local

Rhode Island
  Total Cost
  Federal
  State
  Local

Maine
  Total Cost
  Federal
  State
  Local

New Hampshire
  Total Cost
  Federal
  State
  Local

Vermont
  Total Cost
  Federal
  State
  Local

New England
  Total Cost
  Federal
  State
  Local
Percent
Share
100.0
 50.0
 30.0
 20.0
100.0
 50.0
 25.0
 25.0
100.0
 50.0
 25,9
 25.0
100.0
 50.0
 30.0
 20.0
100.0
 50.0
 40.0
 10.0
100.0
 50.0
 30.0
 20.0
100.0
 50.0
 29.0
 21.0
  Amt.  In
 $M11lions
 $280.5
  140.3
   84.1
   56.1
  438.0
  219.0
  109.5
  104.5
   51.5
   25.7
   12.9
   12.9
  140.9
   70.5
   42.2
   28.2
  138.0
   69.0
   55.2
   13.8
   70.0
   35.0
   21.0
   14.0
1,118.9
  559.5
  324.9
  234.5
  *Refers throughout to local government, metropolitan or regional
   districts
                                  81

-------
                                                Estimated Cost*
               State                             ($ Million)
            Connecticut                            $ 280.5
            Massachusetts                            438,0
            Rhode Island                              51.5
            Maine                                    140.9
            New Hampshire                            138.0
            Vermont                                   70.0

            New England                           $1,118.9


Impact at the State Level

     The financial impact that construction of water pollution control
facilities will have on the New England area will vary from State to
State and from community to community.  Individual communities within
each State will have varying degrees of financial difficulties depend-
ing on such factors as present waste treatment facilities, per capita
income of the community, the property tax base, competing claims on
community resources, and credit rating.

     In general, the financial impact of water pollution control facil-
ity costs on the States as a whole will depend largely on:  (1)  the
amounts of Federal aid available to communities within each State for
the construction of water pollution control facilities, (2) past sewerage
expenditures relative to needs, (3) expenditures of State and local
governments for education, highways, public welfare, etc., and (4) the
fiscal capacity and tax effort of State and local governments.

     Past Sewerage Expenditures:  Another important factor that  has
significant bearing on the financial impact is past expenditures of
State and local governments for sewerage systems to meet needs.   In
other words, has past construction of water pollution control facili-
ties of each New England State kept pace with needs?  In general, the
States have not constructed the needed facilities in the past.  How-
ever, some of the New England States have kept pace with their needs
more than the other States, as indicated by the per capita expendi-
tures in Table 33.

     Table 33 shows the per capita expenditures for capital outlay,
operation and maintenance for sewerage services of State and local
governments for 1957, 1962, 1966 and 1968.  Although the figures include
expenditures other than those for treatment and interceptor sewers,
* The costs utilized in this case study are the State investment
estimates as presented in Table 27, page 59.
                                  82

-------
                                                      TABLE  33
                                                     PER CAPITA
                                       EXPENDITURES  OF STATE AND  LOCAL GOVERNMENTS
                                                  FOR SEWERAGE  SERVICES
00
CJ
      State
Connecticut
Massachusetts
Rhode Island
Maine
New Hampshire
Vermont
New England
                                   Capital Expenditures
                                                                       Total Expenditures
                                                               (Capital, Operation and Maintenance)
1957
$4.39
2.25
4.65
1.36
1.89
0.91
2.57
1962
$8.40
3.83
2.08
2.80
1.65
3.72
3.75
1966
$8.84
3.61
5.92
2.76
4.08
5.14
5.06
1968
$9.97
2.88
3.41
6.33
5.71
11.70
6.67
^ — -, p, .
1957
$6.01
3.65
6.33
2.11
2.53
1.59
3.70
1962
$10.80
5.38
4.72
3.76
2.65
4.86
5.36
1966
$11.35
5.27
8.68
4.25
5.18
6.88
6.94
1968
$13.13
4.98
6.37
7.71
7.56
14.08
8.97
       Source:  "Census of Governments, 1957 and 1962", Bureau of the Census, Washington, D.C,
                "Governmental Finances in 1965-1966", Bureau of the Census, Uashinnton, D.C.
                "Governmental Finances in 1967-68", Bureau of the Census, Washington, D.C.

-------
they serve to Indicate the approximate and relative level of past spend-
ing for water pollution control facilities for each New England State.
For example, in 1957 the per  capita capital expenditures varied greatly
from one State to  another with a high of $4.65 for Rhode Island compar-
ed to a low of $0.91 for Vermont.  The data further indicate that in
1957 the northern  States  (Maine, New Hampshire and Vermont) spent con-
siderably less than the southern States (Connecticut, Massachusetts
and Rhode Island).  However,  in 1968 the capital investment of the
northern States was on the average 50 percent more than the southern
States.  In 1968,  all the New England States, except Rhode Island,
spent more on capital outlay  than in 1957 with Vermont having spent
the most of the six States.

     Needed Expenditores:  Even more significant than past expenditures
for sewerage services are the expenditures needed in the near future
to construct water pollution  control facilities in each of the six
New England States.  By way of comparison, the needed investments on
a per capita basis for constructing water pollution control facilities
for each New England State are:

            Connecticut         $95           Maine           $144
            Massachusetts       $80           New Hampshire   $197
            Rhode  Island        $56           Vermont         $166

     The above figures are based on the cost estimates presented in
Table 32 and 1968  population.

     On the average, the  per  capita costs of needed facilities in the
northern States are double those of the southern States.  The cost of
needed investment  in Vermont  and New Hampshire are the highest, on a
per capita basis,  of all  New  England States.

     A further analysis of the needed investments of each New England
State is presented in Table 34 to evaluate the impact that financing of
water pollution control facilities would have on State and local gov-
ernments.  The annual per capita amounts are based on capital costs
estimates amortized for 25 years at 5.0 percent and 1968 population.
Also included are  the per capita amounts as a percent of total per
capita expenditures of State  and local governments (1968).  (The
total per capita expenditures of State and local governments are shown
in Table 35.)  In  addition, an estimate of the annual per capita amounts
and percentages for operation and maintenance as well as total annual
per capita costs and percentages are given in Table 34 for each New
England State.

     With Federal  aid amounting to 50 percent grants to all projects,
all of the New England States, will be required to commit (based upon
1968 expenditures  rates)  1.6  percent of their total funds
                                   84

-------
                                                          TABLE 34
                                      STATE  AND  LOCAL  GOVERNMENTS'  ANNUAL  EXPENDITURES
                                    FOR  NEEDED PUBLIC  WATER POLLUTION CONTROL FACILITIES
                                            (Based  on  50 Percent Federal Grants)
oo
en
       State
Connecticut
Massachusetts
Rhode Island
Maine
New Hampshire
Vermont
                                     Annual  Equivalent*
                                       Capital  Outlay
                                                              Annual
                                                     Operation and Maintenance
Total
Annual Cost
Per
Capita
Amounts
$3.36
2.86
2.16
5.10
6.98
5.88
Percent
of 1968
Expend.
0.6
0.6
0.4
1.1
1.6
0.9
Per
Capita
Amounts
$4.74
4.03
2.83
7.20
9.83
8.29
Percent
of 1968
Expend.
0.9 '
0.8
0.5
1.5
2.2
1.3
Per
Capita
Amounts
$8. 1C
6.89
4.99
12.30
16.81
14.17
Percent
of 1968
Expend.
1.5
1.4
0.9
2.6
3.8
2.2
       Note:   These columns  indicate  the  per capita  amounts  (based on  capital cost estimates amortized for
              25 years  at 5.0 percent and 1968 populations)  and  the  percent of 1968 expenditures  (based on
              the per capita amounts  and  the total 1968  per  capita expenditures for State and  local governments
              in Table  35).

-------
to such facilities.  The annual per capita Capital outlay would range
from a low of $2.16 for Rhode  Island to a high of $6.98 for New
Hampshire.  Annual expenditure  required for the operation and mainte-
nance of such facilities could  amount to 0.5 to 2.2 percent of 1968
expenditures of State  and  local governments.  The total annual per
capita cost (capital,  operation and maintenance) would range from a
low of $4.99 for  Rhode Island  to  a high of $16.81 for New Hampshire.

     In summary,  Table 34  shows that the burden will be relatively
greater for Maine, New Hampshire  and Vermont than for the other New
England States.

     Comparison of Other State and Local Government Expenditures:  The
financial  impact  that  the  construction of water pollution control faci-
lities will have  on the States as a whole will depend to a degree on
expenditures of each State for other public functions, such as educa-
tion and highways, relative to the capacity of States to meet these
requi rements.

     A comparison of per capita sewerage expenditures and other State
and  local  government expenditures for fiscal year 1968 is shown in
Table 35.   Shown  are per capita total expenditures, as well as those
for  education, highways, public welfare, local parks and recreation,
sanitation other  than  sewerage and sewerage for each New England State
as well as the United  States averages.  New England sewerage expendi-
tures for  fiscal  1968  amounted to $5-14 per capita, or 1-3 percent of
the  total  expenditures for State  and local governments.  In contrast,
education, highways, and sanitation amounted to $163-206, $58-182, and
$1-6 per capita or 32-40,  11-28,  and less than 1 percent of the total
expenditures, respectively. The  United States average expenditures
for  sewerage amounted  to approximately 2 percent of the total, compared
to education and  highway expenditures at 40 and 14 percent of total
expenditures, respectively.  In 1968, over 50 percent of all expendi-
tures of State and local governments was for education and highways,
while sanitation  and sewerage  amounted to less than 3 percent.

     The past expenditures for sewerage services in relation to the
total expenditures of  State and local governments have not been appre-
ciable in  comparison to those  for education and highways.  Futhermore,
the  amount the three southern  States may be required to spend annually
for  the needed facilities  (on  a per capita basis) is about the same
or less than in the past,  while the three northern States will need
to spend considerably  more annually for capital outlay than they did
in the past.

     Fiscal Capacity of State  and Local Governments:  A factor that is
equally or perhaps more important than those already mentioned is the
                                   86

-------
                                                   TABLE 35
                            PER CAPITA EXPENDITURES OF STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENTS
                                               FISCAL YEAR 1968
       State
                 Total
                 Expendi-
                 tures     Education
                     Local        Sanitation
           Public    Parks and    Other than           All
Highways   Welfare   Recreation   Sewage     Sewerage  Others
00
Connecticut

Massachusetts

Rhode Island

Maine

Mew Hampshire

Vermont

New England

United States
$531
510
555
467
446
649
526
512
$198
163
187
206
178
260
199
206
$73
58
no
89
100
182
102
72
$46
65
70
39
30
55
51
49
$8
5
4
2
4
2
4
7
$5
6
4
2
2
1
3
5
$13
5
6
8
8
14
9
9
$188
208
174
121
124
135
158
164
             Partial Source:   "Governmental Finances in 1967-68"
                              Bureau of the Census, Washington, D.C.

-------
fiscal capacity of State and local governments.  The Advisory Commis-
sion on Intergovernmental Relations defines fiscal capacity as follows:

         "... a quantitative measure intended to reflect the
         resources which taxing jurisdiction can tax to raise
         revenue for purposes.  There are many factors that
         determine the  capacity of a community or State to pay
         for public services including the population's income,
         wealth, business activity, etc., the demands made on
         these resources, and the quantity of governmental
         services.11'

     The economic indicator of most general applicability is income.
Therefore,  the economic indicator that will be used here as a measure
of fiscal capacity is the per capita personal income of each of the
New England States.  Since  taxes are generally paid out of current
Income, a community's income is a measure of its capacity to meet both
public and  private needs.   As fiscal capacity is difficult to evaluate
in absolute terms, only a relative measure will be considered in com-
paring one  State with another.

      The per  capita personal income of each of the New England States
for 1950, 1960  and 1967, as well as New England and the United States
averages are  shown in Table 36.  In 1967, Connecticut had the second
highest per capita personal income of the 50 States and the District
of Columbia.   In  1967,  the  States of Connecticut, Massachusetts and
Rhode Island  ranked above the median income State of the Nation while
the other three New England States ranked below.  Maine's per capita
personal income, which  was  the lowest of all the New England States
in 1967, amounted to only 67 percent of the per capita personal income
of Connecticut.

      It is  evident that the financial impact of constructing waste
treatment facilities will be greater in the northern New England States
based on the  following  two  factors:  (1)  the per capita personal
income is less  and is projected to be less in the future for the three
northern States than  for the southern States2, and (2) the estimated
per capita  cost of needed water pollution control facilities in the
northern New  England States is considerably greater than in the south-
ern New England States.
 1  "Measures of State and Local  Fiscal  Capacity and Tax Effort,"  The
   Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental  Relations, p.c.

 2  "Protective Economic Studies  of New  England," Corp of Engineers,
   Waltham, Massachusetts, Part  II, Appendix G.

-------
                             TABLE 36
                      PER CAPITA PERSONAL INCOME
    State                      1950         1960          1967

Connecticut
Massachusetts
Rhode Island
Maine
New Hampshire
Vermont
New England
United States
1,875
1,633
1,606
1,185
1,323
1,121
1,601
1,496
Statistical Abstract of
2,807
2,459
2,211
1,844
2,143
1,841
2,425
2,215
the United States,
3,969
3,541
3,328
2,657
3,053
2,825
3,229
3,159
1967
™«n
             "Governmental Finances in 1967-68" Bureau of the
             Census, Washington, D.C., p. 52
                                89

-------
     Tax Effort:  The extent  to which a State makes use of its fiscal
or taxable capacity  is  defined as tax effort.  For example, if State
X and State Y have the  same fiscal capacity, but State X collects more
taxes than State Y,  then  State X is making a greater tax effort than
State Y.

     A comparison of revenue  of State and local governments for each
of the six States is used as  a relative measure of the tax effort in
New England.  Table  37  indicates the per capita general revenue, of
State and local governments for fiscal 1968, including total general
revenue, revenue from the Federal government, all revenue from own
sources, and  revenue from property taxes.

     The per  capita  total  general revenue in fiscal 1968 ranged from
a low of $400 for Maine to a  high of $579 for Vermont.  However, the
per capita revenue from the Federal government was $74 for Maine com-
pared to $158 for Vermont. A more realistic economic indicator in
evaluating tax effort is  the  revenue collected from State and local
governmental  sources.   For example, in 1968, Massachusetts collected
the highest per capita  revenue ($456) of all six States and Maine the
lowest  ($326).  The  United States average for the same year was $420.
The States of Connecticut, Vermont and Massachusetts were the same or
above the United States average while the other three States were below,
Per capita revenue collected  from property taxes ranged from a high of
$204 in Massachusetts to  a low of $129 in Maine  compared to a United
States average of $139.

     The relation of State and local governments' revenue per $1,000
of per capita personal  income is also included in Table 37.  On this
basis, Rhode  Island  and Vermont had the highest tax effort of the six
States in fiscal 1968,  being  greater than the United States average.

Table 38 presents the relationship of State and local  governments'
annual expenditures  for their share of needed water pollution control
facilities to total  general revenue and property tax capabilities.
Also shown in Table  38  are the per capita amounts as percent of total
general revenue and  property  tax revenue of State and local governments
for 1968.

     With Federal aid amounting to 50 percent of construction cost,
all of the New England  States will be required to commit (based upon
1968 revenue  rates)  1.7 percent or less of their total general revenue
to such facilities.  The  annual capital expenditures for needed water
pollution control facilities  as a percent of property tax revenue would
amount to 1.8 percent or  less for the southern States compared to 4.2
percent for the northern  States.  The additional percentages for annual
operation and maintenance  for the needed facilities range from 0.6 to
2.4 percent of total general  revenue compared to 1.9 to 6.0 percent
of property tax revenue.
                                  90

-------
                              TAPLE 37
          GENERAL REVENUE OF STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENTS
                         FISCAL YF.AR 1968
                            (Per Capita)
                                      All Revenue
                                      From Own
                                      Sources
Relation of
State & Local
Gov't. Revenue
Connecticut
Massachusetts
Rhode Island
Maine
New Hampshire
Vermont
United States
Total
General
Revenue
$50k
534
492
400
412
579
506
From
Federal
Gov't.
$81
78
103
74
79
158
86
Including
Property
Taxes
$421
186*
456
204*
389
146*
326
129*
333
165*
421
138*
420
139*
Per $1 ,
Persona
Income
$126
151
164
151
135
205
160
  Partial  Source:   "Governmental  Finances in 1967-68," P-ureau
                    of the Census, Washington, D.C., p. 31-33

                    *Figures represent revenue from property taxes
                                 91

-------
VO
rvj
   State

Connecticut

Massachusetts

Rhode Island

Maine

New Hampshire

Vermont
                                                  TABLE  38
                        RELATIONSHIP  OF  STATE  AND  LOCAL GOVERNMENTS' ANNUAL  EXPENDITURES
                         FOR  NEEDED WATER  POLLUTION  CONTROL  FACILITIES TO TOTAL GENERAL
                                     REVENUE AND PROPERTY TAX  CAPABILITIES
                                      (Based on 50 Percent Federal Grants)
Annual Equivalent*
Capital Outlay


Per
Capita
Amounts
$3.36
2.86
2.16
5.10
6.98
5.88
Percent
of 1968
Total
General
Revenue
0.7
0.5
0.4
1.3
1.7
1.0
Percent
of 1968
Revenue
from
Property
Taxes
1.8
1.4
1.5
4.0
4.2
4.2
Annual
Operation and Maintenance


Per
Capita
Amounts
$4.74
4.03
2.83
7.20
9.83
8.29
Percent
of 1968
Total
General
Revenue
0.9
0.8
0.6
1.8
2.4
1.4
Percent
of 1968
Revenue
from
Property
Taxes
2.5
2.0
1.9
5.6
6.0
6.0


Per
Capita
Amounts
$8.10
6.89
4.99
12.30
16.81
14.17
Total
Annual Cost
Percent
of 1968
Total
General
Revenue
1.6
1.3
1.0
3.1
4.1
2.4
Percent
of 1968
Revenue
from
Property
Taxes
4.3
3.4
3.4
9.6
10.2
10.2
       Note:   *These columns  Indicate per capita  amounts  (based on  capital  costs  amortized for 25 years
               at 5.0 percent and 1968 populations)  and percentages (based  on  the per capita  amounts  and
               total  general  revenue and  property tax revenue of State and  local  qovernments  for 1968,
               Table 37).

-------
     In summary, the financial impact of constructing water pollution
control facilities certainly will be relatively greater for the States
of Maine, New Hampshire and Vermont, than for Connecticut,  Massachusetts
and Rhode Island, based on per capita construction costs of waste  treat-
ment facilities, per capita personal income, and State and  local govern-
mental expenditures and revenues.

Impact at the Community and Homeowner Levels

     Quite apart from any assumptions with respect to the availability
of Federal and State aid, local communities in New  England will face
varying degrees of difficulties in financing their share of the total
cost of waste treatment and collection facilities.  Once they know
what their share of the cost is and proceed with bond issues to
finance it, they face alternative means of recapturing these costs,
i.e., repayment of bond issues.  These problems may be intensified
by the fact that, in many New England communities, an industry domi-
nates the local econ4my, thus raising the very important question  of
whether repayment should be in the form of a sewer service  charge  or by
means of general taxation, or a combination of both.

     In general, the financial impact of water pollution control
facilities at the community level will depend largely on the existence
of present water pollution control facilities, per capita income of
the community, property tax base, competing claims on community
resources and credit ratings.

     The percentage of the local share that will be shouldered directly
by homeowners will depend on the alternative means of repayment of bond
issues used by a community, i.e., whether repayment is in the form of
a sewer service charge or by means of general property taxation.   It
is important to realize that, in the final analysis, the cost of sewer-
age facilities is paid for directly and  indirectly by all taxpayers,
but the impact on property owners will vary with the method of
financing.

     In order to evaluate the financial  impact at the community  and
homeowner levels, a number of alternative financial arrangements will
be considered.

     Alternative Financial Arrangements:

          The Funding Problem:   Although Federal and State grants  are
available to local communities for water pollution control facilities,
the communities must finance  their share of the cost.   In general,
most of the cities and towns  in  New England will depend on municipal
bond issues to finance the local share,  but they will have varying
degrees of difficulties in financing, due to municipal  credit ratings,
legal  bonded debt limits  and  market conditions.
                                  93

-------
           Bond  Issues  and  Municipal Credit Rating:  The two types of
bonds most widely used  to finance water pollution control facilities
are general obligation  and  revenue bonds.  In the case of general obli-
bonds, the town  or  city pledges  its full credit for repayment of the
debt from the  general tax fund or service  charges.  Such bonds in effect
constitute a tax lien on all  assessable property in the community.  In
contrast, a revenue bond is an obligation  issued to finance a revenue
producing enterprises,  payable exclusively from earnings of the enter-
prise, in this case service charges.   Since the repayment of revenue
bonds is dependent  on the earnings of  the  enterprise, these bonds usual-
ly carry an interest rate that is 1/2  to 1 percent higher than general
obligation bonds.

     An important factor In determining the interest rate a community
must pay for municipal  bonds  is  the credit rating of the community.
Credit ratings are  determined by such  national firms as Moody's Inves-
tors Service,  Inc.  and  Standard  & Poor's Corporation and indicate the
community's ability and willingness to repay the bonds.  Investors
charge communities  interest rates that are commensurate with their
credit ratings.

     Moody's rates  the  bonds  of  communities that have $600,000 or more
of debt.  Their  credit  ratings are as  follows:

        Aaa -  Best  Quality
        Aa  -  High  Quality  (generally  known as high grade bonds)
        A-l -  Upper Medium  Grade
        A   -  Upper Medium  Grade (elements exist that suggest suscepti-
                                                 bility to impairment)
      Baa-1 -  Lower Medium  Grade
        Baa -  Lower Medium  Grade (Neither  highly protected nor poorly
                                                             secured)
         Ba -  Some  Speculative Elements
          B -  Speculative
        Caa -  Poor  Standing
         Ca -  Very  poor Prospects of Payment
          C -  Lowest Rated  Class

     Many characteristics of  a community are evaluated to arrive at a
credit rating.   The most important elements used by Moody's In deter-
mining a rating  for a community  are, (1) management (the policies of
the community  in regard to  fiscal matters), (2) the economy of the com-
munity (the presence of industry and commercial establishments within
the municipality as  well as its  capital program), and (3)the bonded
debt.  Several other tangibles and intangibles influence a rating.

     Moody's rating  for the New  England States and a number of selected
communities are  given in Table 39.  The State of Rhode Island has an
A-l rating, Massachusetts, an Aa rating and the other four States, Aaa
                                  94

-------
                           TABLE 39
                       MOODY'S RATINGS
                            OF
            NEW ENGLAND STATES AND SELECTED COMMUNITIES
                       (December 1969)

State and Community                           Ratlnq

Connecticut                                    Aaa
     Groton                                    A-l
     Hartford                                  Aaa
     Plainfield                                A
Maine                                          Aaa
     Bangor                                    Aa
     Caribou                                   Baa-1
Massachusetts                                  Aa
     Amesbury                                  A
     New Bedford                               A
New Hamoshire                                  Aaa
     Concord                                   Aaa
     Hudson                                    A
Rhode Island                                   A-l
     Barrinqton                                Aa
     Warwick                                   Baa-1
     Woonsocket                                Baa
Vermont                                        Aaa
     Brattleboro                               Aa
     Montpelier                                Aaa
                               95

-------
ratings.  In general, the communities In New England have a lower rat-
Ing than their respective States.

     In November  1969, the interest rates for Aaa, Aa, A and Baa ratings
were 6.05, 6.34,  6.65 and 6.83 percent, respectively.  In general, a
difference of 0.1 percent In the interest rate on a $1 million bond
issue  (20 year maturity) would cost taxpayers or users $20,000 more.
For instance, the State's share of the cost of waste treatment facilities
for Massachusetts is estimated to be $110 million.  Based on the present
trend  in interest rates  and 20 year maturity, it would cost taxpayers
or users approximately $6 million less to repay the State's share if
the State of Massachusetts had a credit rating of Aaa instead of Aa.

               Legal Bonded Debt:  Another factor that may create a
funding problem for local communities In financing water pollution
control facilities  is their legal bonded debt limit.  All communities
have a legal debt limit  for public works construction, but in all New
England States,   except  Maine, water pollution control facilities and
school construction are  not included under the debt limit specified by
law.

     Although water pollution control facilities may be exempt from the
legal  debt limit  there is a question as to what extent a community
should exceed its legal  debt limit.  As a general guide, the Interna-
tional City Manager's Association suggests that (1) the ratio of in-
debtedness to full  taxable value should not exceed 10 percent, and
(2) debt retirement should be so scheduled that at least 25 percent
of the principal  is always due for amortization within a five year
period.  Moody's  Investors Service, Inc. suggests that a total debt
service requirement (interest and retirement of principal) which is
more than 15 percent of  the community's normal annual budget may be
considered high,  but also points out that no strict rule of thumb can
be applied since  in communities with financial difficulties, even 10
percent may be too  high.

     In summary,  the funding problem will vary from community to com-
munity as reflected by the type of bond issues, credit ratings and
legal  bonded debt limits of each community.

          The Repayment Problem:

               General Property Taxation:  Many communities in New
England are repaying municipal bonds, including those issued for water
pollution control  facilities out of revenue collected from property
taxes.  To evaluate the impact of financing waste systems on the local
community, the increase in property taxes on a $20,000 home (market
value) under various conditions of aid availability will be considered
for several  communities in each of the New England States.  Each
community was selected to represent various magnitudes of investment.
                                 96

-------
     It was assumed that the method of financing would be general obli-
gation bonds (25 year maturity).  An interest rate of 5.0 percent was
used for all communities although the actual interest rate each  commu-
nity will pay depends upon its credit rating and market conditions.
The capital costs used are preliminary estimates and may not reflect
the actual costs to each community.

     Table 40 indicates the effect on property taxes for a $20,000 home
(market value) for each of the selected municipalities under conditions
of (!) 50 percent Federal aid and 25-40 percent State aid, (2) no
Federal aid and 25-40 percent State aid, and (3) no Federal and  State
aid.  The annual tax increase is attributable to the cost of water
pollution control facilities, i.e., annual amortized capital cost plus
the estimated annual cost of operation and maintenance.  The three
chosen to evaluate the financial impact on the selected municipalities
under extreme conditions (full aid and no aid) and under an intermediate
condition (State aid only). Even though the second and third assumptions
may not be realistic, they serve to measure the financial impact.

      The total 1968 property taxes on a $20,000 home for the selected
communities ranged between $360 and $1061.  The new annual property
taxes ranged between $413 and $1095 under conditions of maximum  aid
available; $440 and $1146, State aid only, and $453 and $1168, no aid.
These figures include the annual capital, operation and maintenance
costs of waste treatment facilities and are based on 1968 assessed
valuations, assessment ratios and tax rates.

      The annual increase in property taxes needed to finance the
facilities ranged between $11 and $75 under maxmum aid; $20 and  $126,
State aid only; and $28 and $160, no aid.  Of the 16 selected commu-
nities, all had an annual tax increase of $75 or less under conditions
of maximum aid compared to 11 communities with State aid only, and  9
communities without Federal or State aid.

      It is important to emphasize that these figures do not include
the cost of a collection system, and, to estimate more accurately
the impact on a homeowner not served by a sewer system, an annual
cost for a collection system must be added to the above figures. An
average annual cost of $50-$75 per household for a collection system
would result in a total annual cost of $61 to $150 under maximum aid
for a $20,000 home for the collection and treatment of sewage.  The
total annual cost of collection and treatment per $20,000 home would
range between $70 and $201 under State aid only, and between $78 and
$235 under conditions of no aid for the selected communities.

               Service Charges:  A number of New England communities
use a sewer service charge, also called a rental charge, use charge or
sewer use tax as a source of revenue to repay general obligation, or
revenue bonds used to finance waste treatment facilities and/or  to  pay
                                  97

-------
                                    TABLE 40
EFFECT ON PROPERTY TAX ON A $20,000 HOME IN FINANCING WASTE TREATMENT FACILITIES
                                 (MARKET VALUE)
      State and Conmunlty

      Connecticut
           Groton
           Canton
           Plalnfleld

      Maine
           Banqor
           Caribou
           Farmlngdale

oo     Massachusetts
           Amesbury
           New Bedford
           Rockport

      New Hampshire
           Concord
           Conway
           Dover
           Hudson

      Rhode Island
           Jamestown
           Woonsocket

      Vermont
           Brattleboro
           Windsor
                     1968
                     Taxes
                    $570
                     564
                     360
                     668
                     609
                     388
                    1020
                    1061
                     455
                     877
                     440
                     691
                     620
                     380
                     737
                     747
                     721
                              Increase 1n Annual Taxes
Max.
Aid

$25
20
53
36
49
49
75
16
16
54
21
11
68
34
21
26
33
State
Aid
Only
$48
40
96
60
81
80
126
34
30
94
30
20
120
60
38
46
59
No
Aid

$ 60
49
120
76
101
100
148
39
36
128
37
28
160
73
45
58
76
  New Annual Taxes
Max7
 704
 658
 437
 931
 461
 702
 688
 414
 758
 773
 754
State
Aid
Only
 728
 690
 468
 971
 470
 711
 740
 440
 775
 793
 780
 No
 Aid
$595    $618     $630
 584     604      613
 413     456      480
 744
 710
 488
1095
1077
471
1146
1095
485
1168
1100
491
1005
 477
 719
 780
 453
 782
 805
 797

-------
for the cost of operation and maintenance of the system.  Other commu-
nities use a combination of service charges, general  taxes  and better-
ments.  For example, in Brockton, Massachusetts, 50 percent of sewerage
revenue is from service charges, 25 percent from betterments  and 25
percent from general taxation.

     The sewer service charges can be based on one or a combination of
factors such as the following:  metered volume of water used, flat
rates, sewage flow and/or strength, property frontage or area, value
of property or number of rooms.

     Basing the service charge on the metered volume  of water use is
one of the most frequently selected methods, since 85 percent of the
water distributed in the Nation is metered.  With this method, the
charge can be based on a uniform metered volume of water used, sliding
scale of metered water used, block ratio of water used, percentage of
water bill or by the size of the water meter.

     Flat rates, which are used in areas where metered water service
is not available, can be based on the number of equivalent dwelling
units, number of persons residing or working on the premises, number
of plumbing fixtures, and/or the number of sewer connections.  The
disadvantage of the flat rate basis is the users are not charged in
terms of quantity or quality discharged into the system.

     The metered sewage charge is usually limited to industry  and
commercial establishments and some inter-municipal arrangements be-
cause of the cost and technical  difficulty in metering the quantity
and quality if it were feasible  to meter on a widespread basis.

     Example I which is presented later compares a service charge with
general taxation for a large  industry within a  small community.

               The  Problem of Joint or Separate  Facilities

     Explanation of Distinction:  For the purpose of this report,  a
separate facility is defined  as  one where the wastes are from municipal
sources which include domestic,  commercial,  and a small amount of  in-
dustrial wastes while a joint facility is one that receives domestic,
commercial, and a large amount of industrial wastes.  However, in  both
cases, the  facilities are  constructed as well as owned and operated
by  the municipalities.  The  first example  to  follow was selected to
compare the impact  of a service  charge with  that of  general taxation
1n  the case of  a joint  treatment system.

      In a number of the smaller towns in Northern New England, one
major  industry  produces exceptionally large  pollution  loads compared
to  the total  load discharged.   In such town,  the waste  load from the
community mav have  a biochemical oxygen  demand  (BOD)*  load of 500 -
l!ooO  Ibs/dtJ while the  industry's  load  may be  60,000  to 100,000 Ibs/day

* Biochemical Oxygen  Demand - The amount of oxygen required by living
   micro-organisms in  the  decomposition of organic  matter in water.

                                  99

-------
     By  law, the  Industry Is  required to treat its waste, but 1t may do
this by  (1) building  Its  own  treatment facility, or (2) having the
community build a treatment facility which the industry and the commun-
ity can  use jointly.   However,  the  latter alternative has prompted some
to question whether the amount  of Federal and State assistance to a
community constructing a  joint  facility serving a dominant industry
should be reduced.  ABT Associates  in their report to the FVIPCA, sub-
sequently transmitted to  the  Congress, on incentives to industry
recommended:

     "...it does  not  seem desirable to continue to give grants
     to  municipalities to construct industrial treatment faci-
     lities.   Instead, the current  practice should be changed
     so  that grants are only  given  for the percentage of
     capacity  which is actually used to treat domestic wastes.
     Towns should be  required to allocate costs between indus-
     trial and other  wastes according to standarized procedures."!

The report further mentions that:

     "The present value to the  firm of the tax savings for
     pollution control spending under the current tax law is
     30% to 45% of the cost of  the  capital investment and 50%
     of  any operating costs.  The very substantial size of
     this aid  should  be kept  in mind when considering the
     argument  often made  for  additional tax assistance, namely,
     that the  community as a  whole  ought to assume part of the
     costs for abating pollution.   Whether it should or not,
     the community is already In fact assuming much of the
     burden to industrial  pollution control." 2

     Example I illustrates the  costs to both the industry and the town
if a joint facility is constructed  compared to separate facilities.

     Example I

     A small community with a large paper company located in the town
is used  for this  example.  It is estimated that the cost of required
water pollution control facilities, including collection and treatment,
for the  town alone  is $500,000  while a system that could accommodate
both the industry and the  town  is estimated to cost $6 million.  For
the purpose of this analysis, the following assumptions were made:
1  ABT Associates Inc., "Incentives to Industry for Water Pollution
   Control:  Policy Consideration," December 1967, p. 54.

2  Ibid., p. 41
                                  100

-------
Federal aid 50 percent and State aid 30 percent of construction  costs,
25 year amortization period, 5.0 percent interest rate on general  obli-
gation bonds, and annual costs of operation and maintenance as 5 percent
of capital costs.  Total costs eligible for State and Federal  assistance
are approximately $5.9 million for the joint facility.

     The waste characteristics for the town and the industry are as
fol1ows:

Waste Characteristics                  Town              Industry

Flow-mgd.                               0.25                10.7

Biochemical Oxygen Demand (BOD) -     500                 63,100
   Ibs/day

Suspended Solids - Ibs/day            500                292,4000

     This means that the industry's average daily flow is approximately
43 times that of the town, 5 day BOD is 126 times, suspended solids  is
585 times and the cost  approximately 11 times.  What financial arrange-
ment would be most equitable for the industry and the town?  Should  the
town pay 1/43, or 1/126, or 1/585 of the annual cost of the joint
facility and the industry the  remainder?  The following analysis will
consider the cost to the town  and to the industry based on general prop-
erty taxes, cost distribution, flow, BOD and suspended solids.  It is
not the intent of this  example to develop a scheme for equitably distri-
buting costs of a joint facility between the town and industry, but
to present a number of  possible alternatives that can be used in deter-
mining an equitable cost-sharing arrangement.  The financial
arrangement is shown as follows:

                            Joint Facility

Total  Cost of Joint Facility                         $ 6,000,000

     Eligible Costs                                    5,900,000

     Federal Share - 50%                               2,950,000

     State Share - 30%                                 1,770,000

     Local Share - 20%                                 1,180,000
                                    101

-------
Total Local Share  (Includes
$100,000 ineligible costs for
collection system) -                                 $ 1,280,000
Annual Capital Cost (amortized
25 yrs. 95.0X)                                           90,800
Annual Operation  and
Maintenance Costs  -                                      300,000
Total Annual  Cost -                                  $   390,800
Cost Sharing
General  Property  Taxes
      If the  annual  cost of  $390,800 were to be financed from property
tax  revenue,  then an  increase in  the tax rate would necessary:
Total  assessed value  of all  property (1969)          $18,943,060
Total  assessed taxes  (1969)                            1,006,733
Tax  rate (per $1,000  valuation)                               53
New  Taxes   ($1,006,733 + 390,800)                      1,397,533
New  Tax rate  (per $1,000 valuation)                           74
 Increase in  Tax Rate                                  	?!
 Industry's Share  of Joint Facility
 (1969 industry's  assessed evaluation,
$12,185,400)                                          $251,700  64.4%
Town's Annual Share of Joint Facility
 (1969 assessed valuation, commercial
 and  residential $6,757,660)                           139,100  35.62
 Service Charge
 1.   If the cost-sharing were to  be  based on  flow, then:
     Town's Annual  Share -                     $ 9,000     2.3%
     Industry's Annual Share -                $  381,800    97.7%
2.   If the cost-sharing were to  be  based on  5  day BOD, then:
     Town's Annual  Share -                     $ 3,100     0.8%
                                  102

-------
    Industry's Annual Share -                 $ 387,700    99.2%

3.  If the cost-sharing were to be based on suspended solids,  then:

    Town's Annual Share -                         $ 800     Q.2%

    Industry's Annual Share -                 $ 390,000     99.8%

     The cost to the town will vary greatly depending on whether or  not
general taxation or a service charge based on flow, BOD or suspended
solids is used to repay the general obligation bonds for a joint faci-
lity.  A summary of the total annual costs (capital, operation and
maintenance) to the community and the industry is tabluated below:

                           Joint Facility

                        (Total Annual Costs)

General Taxes	Service Charge Based On	
                            Flow	      Bod	  Suspended Solids
Cost  Percent          Cost    Percent  Cost  Percent   Cost    Percent
in                      in               in              in
$1,000                 $1,000           $1,000          $1,000

Town
$139.1   35.6          $ 9.0     2.3      3.1    0.8      0.80    0.2

Industry
$251.7   64.4          $381.8   97.7    387.7   99.2    $390.0   99.8

      It is evident with a joint facility that the town would pay a
higher percentage of the total annual cost if general taxation were
used  to raise revenue than  if a service charge were used based on  flow,
BOD or suspended solids.  However,  a more reasonable financial arrange-
ment  would be one in which  the total annual cost to the industry and
the town is determined by construction  and operation costs that are
attributable directly to each.  A  detailed analysis of these costs would
then  be required to  arrive  at a more accurate and equitable service
charge for each.

      Separate Facility:  A  further comparison is considered in this
example to evaluate  the total annual costs to the  town if  a separate
facility were constructed instead  of a  joint system.

                          Separate Facility

Total Cost of Town  Facility                        $ 500,000

      Eligible Costs                                  400,000
                                  103

-------
     Federal Share 50%                               200,000

     State Share 30%                                 120,000

     Local Share 20%                                  80,000

     Total Local Share                               180,000
     Annual Capital Cost
     (25 yr. @ 5.0%)                                  12,800

Annual Operation and  Maintenance Cost                 20,000

     Total Annual Cost                                32,800

     The total annual cost for the town would amount to $32,800 if
the town constructed  and maintained a separate facility.  On the other
hand, if the industry constructed and maintained its own facility,
then its total annual cost would be $642,800 based on no Federal or
State financial assistance.  This would result in our annual reduction
of profits of approximately 4.6$ per share before taxes (1968 proce
range per share, $44  - 29 1/2) based on the number of common shares
outstanding as of December 31, 1968.  The company earned $2.48 per share
in 1968 while dividends amounted to $1.40 per share.

     With a joint facility, the town's annual share would range from
$800 to $139,100 or from 0.2 to 35.6 percent respectively depending on
the method of financing.  In contrast, the industry's annual reduction
of profits for a joint facility would range from 1.8 to 2.8£ per share
before taxes depending on the method of financing and based on full
Federal and State financial assistance.

     If general taxation were used to raise revenue to finance the
annual cost of a joint facility, then the town would pay more than if
the town had its own  separate facility.  However, if a service charge
were used, based on flow, BOD, suspended solids or a combination of
these for a joint facility, the town would pay less annually than having
its own facility.  The reduction in profits to stockholders would not
be that significant if the industry were to construct and maintain its
own facility.  However, the amount of Federal and State aid for a joint
facility would amount to approximately $4.7 million compared to $320,000
for a separate municipal plant.

     Example II

     In the final analysis, part of the cost of financing water
pollution control facilities is borne directly by homeowners and otherr
users and the remainder, namely the Federal and State share, is borne
indirectly by all taxpayers.  The impact on the homeowner can be
evaluated, but the impact on the taxpayers in general cannot.  To
illustrate the impact on the average homeowner, the following example
is presented.


                                 104

-------
     A particular community in New Hampshire  was  selected  because
there is virtually no industry in the town, and the cost of water
pollution control facilities will be borne directly by homeowners.
Although the 1960 population of the town was  3,650, it has nearly
tripled in the past nine years to a present estimated population of
10,000.  The building boom will not continue, however, because  of the
town's new zoning regulations.  Presently, only a small percentage
of the population is sewered, and there are no treatment facilities.
The estimated cost of interceptors and water pollution control
facilities is $1.8 million and the cost of lateral sewers  is  $1.48
million.  The Federal and State aid programs  can provide 90 percent
of the cost of treatment facilities and interceptors, leaving approx-
imately $0.18 million plus $1.48 million or a total of $1.66  million
to be financed by the community.

     In the analysis to follow, the estimated cost of water pollution
control facilities for the average homeowner in this town will  be
compared to the average cost of other utilities such as water,
electricity and telephones.

     The cost of water pollution control facilities to the average
homeowner will vary depending on the funds available and method of
financing used, i.e., general taxes or service charge.  Based on 50
percent Federal aid and 40 percent State aid, the cost to the average
homeowner ($20,000 market value) would amount to approximately  $25 per
year compared to $50 per year if only State aid were available.  If  a
service charge were used, based on a percentage of the water bill,
then the cost for waste treatment facilities for a family of 4  would
amount to approximately $50 per year with  full aid and $100 per year
with State aid and no Federal aid.

     In addition, homes that are not presently sewered will have an
additional betterment charge that may amount to $50-75 per year for
20 years.  For these homeowners, the annual cost of a  collection and
treatment system may range from $75 to $175 depending  on available
funds and the method of financing.

     By way of comparison, the monthly average utility charges  for
a family of four are electricity, $10; water, $7;  and  telephone, $8
(with toll charges $11.50).  These compare to $7 to $15 for waste
treatment and collection,  depending on the availability of funds.
                                  105

-------
                          PRIORITY SYSTEMS

      The Federal Water Pollution Control Act stipulates that no
grant shall be approved for any project unless the project (1) con-
forms with the State's water pollution control nian, and (2) has
been certified by the appropriate State agency as entitled to
priority over other projects on the basis of financial as well as
water pollution control needs.

      From a national point of viev/, it may be assumed that the R'!PCA's
primary objective is pollution abatement and control.  Secondary
objectives include providing financial assistance to local communities
and preserving the State role in pollution control.  With these
objectives and a frame of reference that assumes sufficient monies
are not available to assure that all projects will be funded, the
need for a priority system overrides all arguments against one.
The discussion of priority systems here  is within the context of
the only alternative that makes such systems meaningful--scarcity
of funds.  Priority systems assume their greatest significance
when the abatement program must be stretched out over time because
of a scarcity of funds whether local or  federal.  With sufficient
funds available  to assure a massive clean-up over a  relatively
short time frame (e.g., New York State Pure Waters Program) the
significance of  priority systems would diminish.

      In general, development of a priority  system is a  means by which
critical needs or problems can be  identified.   In most cases  this  is
accomplished by  applying several criteria  to  a group of  projects which
permits them to  be ranked in order of  desirability.   The Act  only
requires that each project financially assisted  be entitled to  prior-
ity over the other projects  on a  financial  need  as well  as  a  pollution
control basis.   (This  could  be interpreted that, between two  eligible
projects,  only the project with  the greater financial need would
receive assistance;  and  the  other  project  could  proceed  without
Federal assistance.)

      In Table 41 the  various  criteria the States  use have  been
identified.  They generally  fall  in  three broad categories,  (a) water
pollution  control needs,  (b)  financial needs,  and  (c)  state  of  plan-
ning  and  readiness.   In  some instances,  criteria within  a category^
have  been  aggregated.  These should  be interpreted  as identifying  in
a  general  sense  what types  of criteria are used.   For example,  under
the  heading  abatement  needs,  an  X  indicates the criteria employed
was  either a court order or  project  to  eliminate the discharge  of
inadequately treated wastes, or  eliminate a nuisance, etc.
                                   107

-------
                                                                                                TABLE  41
                                                                                         PRIORITY  SYSTEM  CRITERIA
00
POLLUTION ABATEMENT
Cwnp, Health
Plan Hazard
Alabama
Alaska
Arizona X
Arkansas X
California X
Colorado
Connecticut
Delaware X
District of Columbla(a)
Florida X
Georgia X X
Hawaii
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana X
Iowa X
Kansas X
Kentucky X
Louisiana
Maine
Maryland
Massachusetts
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
New Hampshire
New Jersey
New Mexico
New York
North Carolina
North Dakota
Ohio
Oklahoma
Oregon
Pennsylvania
Rhode Island
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Utah
Vermont
Virginia
Washington
West Virginia
Wisconsin
Wyoml ng
Puerto R1co
X
X

X
X

X


X
X
X
X






X




X

X
X


X
X
Trtrnt.
WQS Reqd,
X
X X
X
X
X
X X
X
X
X
X
X
X X
X




X X
X
X
X
X

X
X X


X
X X
X


X

X
X

X
X X
X
X


Abatmt.
Needs
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X

X
X
X
X
X
X
X

X

X
X

X
X
X
X
X
X

X
X


X
X
X
X
X
X
l.'ater Vol. Inter/
Uses Waste Intra
X
XXX
X X
X X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X X X
X
X

X
X
X
X
X

X X
X
X
X X



X
X

X
X
X
X
X X
X
X X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X X
X
FINANCIAL
F1nan. Inc- Const.
Status one Cost
X
X X
X X X
X X
X
X
X
X X
X
X
X X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X X
X X
X
X
X

X X

X X
X
X
X
X X
X
X
X
X
X

X

X X
X
X
X
X X
X X

X
Pss. Rond.
Val. Debt Poi>, Other
X X
X X
X X X
X X
X
X X
X
X
X X
X
X
X
X
X X X
X
X X


X
X
X X
X
X
X

X
X X


X
X
X

X

X
X
X X
X
X
X X
X
X
X X
PLANNING/READINESS
Site Enqr. Plans
Acqd. Rept. Apprvd.
X X
X X
X
X
X X
X
X
X X
X X

X
X


X
XXX
X

X

X



X X
X

X
X
X
X X
X X
X X
X , X
X X
X X
X X
X X



Flnacng. Contract implmntn. iirant
Arrangd. Awarded Plans Appl.for
X
X
X
X
X X
X
X
X
X
X X

X X
X

X
X X
X
X
X
X
X




X
X

X X
X

X X
X
X
X
X
X
X


X

Priorities Assessed
Independent of
Rrant Applications
Yes No Unk.
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X


X

X
X


X
X
X
X
X



X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
X







X
X

X


X







„







X


X
       (a) Priority system not applicable

-------
                           TABLE 42

       Numerical Rank of Criteria by General  Categories
                                  Need
Alabama
Alaska
Ari zona
Arkansas
California
Colorado
Connecticut
Delaware
District of Columbia
Florida
Georgia
Hawaii
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Maine
Maryland
Massachusetts
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri (a)
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
New Hampshire
New Jersey
New Mexico  (b)
New York
North Carolina
North Dakota
Ohio
Oklahoma
Oregon
Pennsylvania
Rhode Island
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Utah
Vermont
Virginia
Washington
West Virginia
Wisconsin
Wyoming
Puerto Rico
(a) Not Numerical   (b) Single Formula
Pollution
1
3
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
3
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
2
1
1
1
1
1
1
2
1
1
1
2
1
1
1
Financial
2
1
2
2
3
2
2
2
2
3
3
1
2


2
2
2
2
1
2
2
2
2
2
3
2
2
2
2
2
2
1
3
2
1
3
2
2
3
3
3
2
2
1
1
2
1
2
Status of
  Plans

    3
    1
    3
    2
    2
    1
    2
    2
    2

    3
    3
    2
    3

    3
    3
    3

    2
    2
    2
    1

    2
    3
    3
    2
    2
    1
    3
    2
    3
    2
                              109

-------
      With the exception of  the State of Missouri, each State's
criteria system adoots  a numerical  formula w.ith the project receiving
the highest point  total assuming  the highest priority.  By grouping
criteria into three  categories, and considering the numerical values
of each category,  it is possible  to assess which group of needs
assumes the most importance  in a  State.  (See Table 42).  From
this,  it can be seen that  the patterns are not uniform.  Some States
olace more weight  on water pollution needs, others give greater
weight to financial  needs.   In a  few instances, readiness to proceed
produces the highest numerical ooint score.

     On paoer, the criteria  which the States apply appear to be
effective with respect  to  the agency's prime objective—water
pollution control  and abatement.   For most States, pollution control
needs  are assigned the  highest numerical values and thereby receive
the most weight.   In a  few instances, they share equal weight with
a  financial  need or the planning  and readiness category.  However,
as far as the construction grant  application is concerned, there is
no assurance that  the particular  project for which assistance is
requested is the project with the most critical pollution need in that
interdependence with other pollution sources is seldom, if ever,
explicitly  considered.   In most States, and oerhaps in all, the criteria
are  actually aoplied only  to those projects on which applications are
filed.  This  results in ranking the applications in the priority they
stand  in  relation  to each  other,  rather than to some absolute standard
of pollution abatement  effectiveness.  Even if priorities are assigned
to all projects  that can be  identified, onl.y grant applications are
considered  as  the  effective  priority list.

       A review of  grants approved through January 31,  1969
where  construction is complete or under way reveals the following
distribution among communities by population size:

                              TABLE 43
          Distribution  of  FWPCA Grants by Size of Community
                        as  of January 31, 1969

Population  Size               $ Million         % of Grants

   Less than 2,500             173.1               15.3
   2,500  -   5,000             128.1               11.3
   5,001  -   10,000             155.9               13.7
   10,001     25,000            215.7               19.0
   25,001     50,000             150.6               13.3
   50,001    125,000             143.9               12.7
 125,001    250,000             62.5                5.5
 250,001    500,000             36.2                3.2
 500,001 and over               68.8                6.1
        TOTAL                 $1134.8              100.0
                                  no

-------
      It would appear that the existing State criteria systems tend
to favor small communities rather than large ones.  This was certainly
true in the State of Ohio which only in recent years has amended its
procedures so that the city of Cleveland is now eligible to receive
Federal assistance from the construction grant program.  However,
the State priority systems are not entirely the cause for this
prohibition.  Earlier versions of the Act carried a stipulation
against Federal funding for communities whose population exceeded
125,000, but this restriction no longer has an effective application.

                              TABLE 44

             Metropolitan & Non-Metropolitan Distribution
                    of FWPCA Construction Grants,
                             1956-1968
                                         Grants Offered
                                    $Millions           Percent

Communities within SMSA's             659.4               59.7
Communities outside SMSA's
     Less than 2,500                  111.2               10.1
      2,500 -  4,999                    74.0                6.7
      5,000 -  9,999                    78.5                7.1
     10,000 - 24,999                  103.0                9.3
     25,000 - 49,999                    77.9                7.1

           TOTAL                     1103.9              100.0

      Though not analyzed here it could also be argued that smaller
communities are easier to convince  in proceeding to overcome their
waste treatment deficiencies.  Or perhaos they are more financially
stable than the large metropolitan  central city.  In any event it
cannot be said that Federal assistance  has not served the metropoli-
tan areas of the nation.  Since  the beginning of the construction
grants assistance program through December 31, 1968, 59.7% of the
total grant dollars has been applied in metropolitan areas.  By
comparing Tables 43 and 44  it can also  be shown that small communi-
ties (within metrooolitan areas) i.e.,  those under 50,000 population,
received 32% of the total grant  dollars approved.

      The fact that most criteria systems are applied only to grant
applications, and that some States  impose an additional requirement
which stipulates that construction  begin within a specified time
(usually the fiscal year of the  application), nullifies the effec-
tiveness of criteria systems.  They become ineffective, because they
do nothing to assure that critical  pollution needs are served.  It
is, in fact, the accident of readiness  that causes such critical
needs to be fulfilled, nothing in the application of priority systems
contributes to that end.

                                   Ill

-------
       The efficiency of State criteria systems appears  difficult
 to  assess.   Not one State applies a specific test to measure the
 efficiency of investments in terms of water pollution control.   But a
 pragmatic view of the operation of the systems, one that questions
 whether a particular investment results in greater pollution abate-
 ment benefits than a similar investment elsewhere, will  give the
 answer that chance, not formal priorities, is responsible for any
 efficiencies resulting from the use of construction grants.   All
 investments may reduce the discharge of untreated wastes, but there
 is  no assurance that the critical problem affecting the  quality
 of  a waterbody is attacked.  (For example, if two communities discharge
 their wastes into the same stream, State grant entitlement criteria
 would be applied independently to the application received from
 either.  If only the downstream community applied because it was
 "ready to proceed," in all probability the application would be
 certified without considering the impact of the other's  waste.)

       The existing system discourages any State agency from refusing
 to  certify a particular application.  Each year certain  monies are
 allocated to each State, and to deny applications is  to  lose
 Federal assistance.  Applications tend to be routinely certified
 where the benefit from the investment nay not be fully realized
 until additional problems are brought under control.  While  this
 approach may in time improve the quality of the stream,  it is far
 less efficient than allocating scarce resources to where they are
 most needed.

       Equity by definition requires that costs be borne  by those
 who receive the satisfactions derived from such costs (at a  minimum
 in  the case of water pollution abatement,  the residents  of a water-
 shed or all the residents of a State) or by those responsible for
 the cost-imposing damage.

       The priority systems as they are applied must be considered
 to  be a source of aggravated inequity.  (This may be  tacitly
 recognized  in the formal criteria of the States:   none includes an
 explicit recognition of an equity principle.)  The failure to assure
 a measure of equity is attributed to the ultimate reduction  of
 priority to the matter of willingness to proceed.   If ineffective,
 the system  must be inequitable,  since it both denies  the intended
 recipients  the assurance of the  benefits of the most  necessary
 works,  and  it denies those damagers who do construct or  intend to
 construct treatment works the assurance of the preconditions  for
 attainment  of physical  benefits  from those works.

       The State criteria systems  provide a technique by  which proj-
 ects  can  be evaluated.   From an  administrative point of  view, they
 eliminate most  of  the  work which  otherwise would be required  to
 approve the particular applications.   Once a  project  is  approved by
 the State as  eligible  for Federal  assistance  and entitled  to priority
over other  projects  little else needs  to be considered.

                                  112

-------
      From the standpoint of the grant aoplications the priority
system assures minimum delays in the processing of projects that
are ready to proceed.  In theory at least, the"n»ost important aspect
of utilizing criteria as a basis for establishing priorities is the
fact that it tends to guide State agencies to those projects where
the greatest need occurs or exists.  This would be particularly
valuable if the States employed their criteria and established
priorities independent of applications being made for assistance,
but in most cases the criteria systems indicate that priorities are
assessed only on grant applications.  (In some States the "one-year
list" identifies more projects than can be funded.  This may be done
to assure that no matter when the application is made during the
fiscal year, it will be accepted, since the project has previously
been identified, assigned a priority and the "one-year list" does
not have to be amended.)

      Though not specified by every State, the readiness to proceed
concept controls.  Almost all approved grants are under construction
at least by the second year following the grant.  (See Tables 45
and 46).

      Table 45 shows that of the WPC grants approved, which were
completed or under construction as of January 30, 1969, 90 percent
of them were under way within 24 months.  The remaining projects
which took anywhere from 27 to over 72 months of elapsed time to
begin construction, tied up about $40 million in grant funds.  While
this represents a small percentage of the total grant funds involved
there is no logic in tying up the funds, particularly in view of the
scarcity of available resources.  This same logic prevails in defense
of the practice of grants only to communities ready to proceed.

      Table 46 shows the age of grants approved but still pending
and not yet under construction as of December 31, 1968.  Here again
the evidence is strong that most projects begin construction within
two years.  For those orojects whose grants have been approved
beyond two years, approximately $38 million in funds are tied up.

      For the grants approved and still pending after two years and
those which took more than two years to begin construction, the
priority rating is meaningless.  Since most States certify each
application and identify its priority, it would be reasonable to
assume that the projects would be under construction soon after they
are approved.  Given that this condition is possible under the exist-
ing system and does in fact exist, the practical aspects of the
criteria system are suspect.  Projects are delayed for a variety
of reasons, but the undesirability of freezing funds and the strict
application of the "readiness to proceed" principle should result
in a reassessment if not real location.
                                  113

-------
                                                     TABLE 45
                 National  Summary—Elapsed  Time  (Mos.) Between Grant Offer and Construction Start
                    	Months	
Size of Place        0     6     9     12     15     18    21    24    27    30    36    42    48    54    60   72   >72
Under 2500         36.9 47.5  49.4   50.0   51.5   51.1  48.8  55.3  63.0  45.0  55.4  52.1  28.6  59.1  50.041.7  60.3
  2,501-  5,000    14.1 13.4  16.3   15.9   16.2   14.7  15.3  12.3  21.2  23.3  12,5  25.0  25.7   4.5  10.0 33.4  12.6
  5,000- 10,000    14.0 12.7  12.3   11.5   13.9   10.4  13.5  14.0   4.9  10.0   8.9   9.4  21.4  13.6  10,0 16.7  10.1
 10,001- 25.000    13.8 11.6  10.9   12.4    8.4   11.4  11.8   8.8   6.2  10.0   7.2   6.2   7.1   4.5  20.0  8.3   9.4
 25,001- 50,000     6.8   6.2   4.6    5.7    5.3    4.3   5.3   3.5   1.2   0.2   8.9   6.2    -    4.5  10.0   -    3.2
 50,001-125,000     5.2   4.1   2.6    2.4    3.3    3.9   1.8   2.6   2.5   0.3   1.8    -          4.5              3.4
125,001-250,000     2.2   1.8   2.3    0.8    1.0    1.8   2.9   0.9    -    0.3   5.4               4.5
250,001-500,000     1.6   1.3   0.7    0.5     -     1.1   0.6   2.6          -     -          7.1          -         0.2
500,001 and over    5.5   1.5   0.7    0.8    0.5    1.4          -          0.2	0.9

% Grants 1n each
 time period        9.4 47.0  14.8    7.7    4.8    3.4   2.1   1.4   1.0   0.7   0.7   0.4   0.2   0.3   0.1  0.1   5.7

Source:  FWPCA Project Register, January 31, 1969

-------
                                                                     TABLE 46
                                   NATIONAL SUMMARY OF  FWPCA GRANTS APPROVED AND  STILL  PENDING AS OF 12/31/68
                                                             (in  millions of dollars)
TOTAL
# $
ALABAMA
ALASKA
ARIZONA
ARKANSAS
CALIFORNIA
COLORADO
CONNECTICUT
DELAWARE
DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA
FLORIDA
GEORGIA
GUAM
HAWAII
IDAHO
ILLINOIS
INDIANA
IOWA
KANSAS
KENTUCKY
LOUISIANA
MAINE
MARYLAND
MASSACHUSETTS
MICHIGAN
MINNESOTA
MISSISSIPPI
MISSOURI
MONTANA
NEBRASKA
NEVADA
NEW HAMPSHIRE
NEW JERSEY
NEW MEXICO
NEW YORK
NORTH CAROLINA
NORTH DAKOTA
OHIO
OKLAHOMA
OREGON
PENNSYLVANIA
PUERTO RICO
RHODE ISLAND
SOUTH CAROLINA
SOUTH DAKOYA
TENNESSEE
TEXAS
UTAH
VERMONT
VIRGINIA
VIRGIN ISLANDS
WASHINGTON
WEST VIRGINIA
WISCONSIN
WYOMING
TOTALS
~5?
1
g
20
16
15
11
5
3
18
23
1
1
15
18
19
7
31
43
20
10
40
10
5
23
60
21
13
26
4
9
1
9
61
17
17
41
50
5
58
17
5
34
15
25
40
11
7
13
1
18
26
10
4
1009
T371
2.7
2.7
4.1
6.8
1.8
1,4
1.9
3,6
3.8
7.8
0.8
0.7
1.5
5.9
6.2
2.3
1.5
4.9
3.1
2.4
2.2
1.9
1.7
4.5
7.3
2.0
0.8
2.5
0.4
1.8
0.2
0.6
6.6
5.5
0.3
11.1
3.8
1.8
8.9
5.2
4.1
4.8
0.4
5.0
6.2
0.9
1.8
3.0
1.8
1.8
7.4
4.6
0.2
190.1
1968
» $
~re
7
12
15
14
11
1
1
15
20
1
1
4
15
16
7
30
24
14
4
32
10
2
20
28
15
9
14
4
6

7
45
17
8
25
26
4
55
5
3
19
10
17
28
4
4
7
1
15
g
6

684
TQT2
2.7
3.6
6.4
1.4
1.4
(a)
2.3
3.0
6.3
0.8
0.7
0.2
4.6
5.5
2.3
1.5
3.4
1.6
1.2
1.2
1.9
0.4
4.4
3.8
1.3
0.7
1.0
0.4
1.1

0.4
3.4
5.5
0.2
&.S
2.7
1.7
8.5
1.5
1.1
2.6
0.2
4,0
3.9
0.1
0.4
2.6
1.8
1.5
1.2
2.3

129.2
1967
» $
~T

5
1


1

3
1


3
2
1

1
13
4
4
4

1

21
4
3
8



2
9

6
12
10

1
7

5
3
6
5
2
1
2

1
5
3
3
170
~OT5

0.2
0.4


1.3

0.8
0.8


0.5
0.1
0.2

(a)
1.1
0.2
0.1
0.5

0.1

1.2
0.1
(a)
1.4



0.2
2.0

0.1
2.0
0.5

Ca)
2.4

0.3
0.2
0.3
1.9
(a)
0.3
0.2

0.2
2.1
1.1
0.1
23.4
1966
* $
T
1

2

1

2


1


5




3
1
1
1

2
2
7
1
1
3

1
1

3

3
2
14

2
1
1
1
2
1
6
5
I
1

2
7

1
93
~274
2.7

0.1

0.4

0.3


0.3


0.2




0.2
0.6
0.5
(a)

1.3
0.1
2.0
0.5
0.1
0.1

0.3
0.2

0.3

(a)
0.3
0.6

0.4
0.2
2.3
(a)
(a)
0.2
0.4
0.8
0.7
0.1

0.1
2.2

0.1
21.0
1965 1964 1963 1962 1961 1960 1959
»$#$»$#$#$#$»J

1
1



1
2

1


1
1
2


2


1



1
1



1


2


2

1


1
5





1


3
1

32

(a)
0.2



0.3
1.3

0.4


(a) 1 0.2 1 0.3
1.2
0.7


n.2 1 (a)
1 0.7
1 0.6
0.2 1 0.1 1 0.2


1 (a)
0.2 2 0.1 1 (a)
0.1

1 (a)

0.1 1 0.3


0.3 1 0.1 1 0.5


0.3

0.1

4 1.1
0.7
1.1 1 0.1 2 0.1 1 0.6

1 0.5
1 (a)

1 0.4
(a) 2 0.1


1.6 2 0.2 1 0.1
1.2

10.2 15 3.6 8 0.8 4 1.1 1 0.1 1 0.2 ] 0.5
          (a) less than $50,000.

Source: FWPCA Project Register 12/31/68

-------
      Looking at the criteria  in another manner, they are very
comprehensive because they  address  themselves to a variety of
categories.  Therefore,  if  many communities  in a State were compet-
ing for Federal assistance, the priority system would screen'them
very effectively.  However, communities do not generally compete
to construct this  type of public investment.  To the contrary, the
State of Maryland  perhaps expresses the attitudes of communities
in this respect.   The following excerpt was  taken from the FY 1968
Maryland State Program Plan:

           "...Almost without exception, every sewerage project
           in Maryland has been undertaken at the suggestion,
           urging,  insistence,  formal  orders, and, when administra-
           tive procedures are  exhausted, by court action initiated
           by the Health  Department  and the Board of Health and
           Mental Hygiene.

           "...Because the application for a grant is made only
           after the community  agrees  to proceed with the con-
           struction of the  project, a hard and fast listing of
           the priority in which applications will be considered
           is ill-advised if not unworkable...In Maryland's
           situation it would be the height of folly to tell
           some community, after a long and bitter struggle to
           get them to act,  that they  would have to wait for
           financing not  because the money wasn't available,
           but because someone  higher  on the predetermined
           priority list  has not yet caved in.

           "In Maryland,  we  have not reached the ooint where
           applicants are eager and  competing for grants to build
           sewage treatment  works.   There are too many other
           competing needs....making demands on their limited
           capacities to  borrow and  spend to do anything that
           is not necessary.  They build only what they are
           forced to build and  only  then if there are rederal
           and State grants  immediately available	"

      The  above quote perhaps  covers  most State/community relations
in this regard.  It indicates  that  it may be illogical to require
State priorities on each application.  In this instance the State
treats applications on a first come first served basis.  One might
assume from the statement that the  State devoted its efforts to
those pollution problems deemed most critical and that they treat
them on some oriority basis in the  first place, so that their
success might likely follow the priorities originally determined.
A more realistic interpretation, however, would take the view that
bargaining power would prevail in such a situation.  All other
things being equal, the  larger unit has more bargaining clout and
is the greater polluter.  Thus, action flows from the least impor-
tant to the most important  element--a reversal of logical priority
operation.
                                  116

-------
      However, since State political leverage en a community may
be presumed to be inversely related to cost effectiveness of
investment, it is not difficult to see why the small community
often builds its plant first.  Then, because of inadequate improve-
ment in stream quality, its weight is added to pressures for action
by the larger community or industry.  However obvious the situation
the way to implementation of the most cost effective investments
first has not been so obvious.

      Perhaps this insures—assuming the pattern is the same in
every State—that the majority of the aoolications received will
come from those communities which are ready to proceed.  They
represent the communities who have been worked over, so to speak,
and who have "caved in."  If this is the real world, the need for
a priority system with an elaborate set of criteria does not exist.
VJhat is needed is simoly more direct and immediate attention paid
to the benefits derived from the project, i.e., improved water
quality, or stream standards satisfied.  Furthermore, unless these
conditions or benefits are oresent, no grant should be ar>oroved.

      It would appear, as in Maryland, communities are not compet-
ing for grants to build sewage treatment works.  Table 47 shows that
year by year there are unused allotments of the construction grant
funds.  Yet, the total grant applications and funds requested are
always greater than the monies available for grants.

      Although the total amounts may be small when comoared to
entire allocations for each year, it is interesting to note that
several of the States have large deficiencies as far as waste
treatment is concerned.  There may be many reasons for the monies
remaining unused, but an obvious one is that in those States,
communities are not competing for funds made available to them.

      In practical terms, the criteria used to develop priorities
among projects obviously has worked and has allocated funds;
however, it must be concluded that the systems as currently
constituted cannot be made workable with respect to establish-
ing priorities on the basis of abatement need because of the
inherent bias toward readiness to proceed as a dominant criterion.

     Although desirable, the State priority systems as a basis
for establishing oriorities among construction projects for
receiving Federal assistance do not satisfy any of the four tests
used to evaluate them.  They are neither effective, efficient,
equitable, nor practical as far as the agency's water pollution
control objective is concerned.
                                  117

-------
                                                TABLE 47
States

Alaska
Delaware
Hawaii
Idaho
Maine
Mississippi
Montana
Nevada
New Hampshire
New Mexico
North Dakota
Rhode Island
South Carolina
South Dakota
Utah
Vermont
Wyomlng
Guam
Puerto R1co
Virgin Islands
                              Federal Water Pollution Control Administration
                                    Division of Construction Grants
                                           Analysis Branch

                                   Unused Allotments by Fiscal Year
                                       (In millions of dollars)
1957-58
$0.85

0.26

0.77






0.20

0.22


(a)
1959
$0.18



0.13
0.43

0.17



0.11
0.07
0.60


0.23
1960
$0.30



0.37


0.09



0.22
0.51
0.43


0.06
1961
$0.42 !


0.08
0.37
0.11


0.18

0.42
0.02
0.23
0.31

0.11
0.44
(Not eligible under program until
0.39
1.65
0.47
0.81
1.10
0.82
0.83
0.82
1962
& (a)*


0.01






0.58


0.12


0.56
FY 1963}
0.64
1.25
1963
$0.39


0.13

0.20
0.27



0.80


0.10
0.54

0.45
1.38
0.04
1.38
1964
$0.68


0.89

0.11
0.88



1.28
0.14

1.21
0.49
0.41
0.88
1.52
0.54
1.35
1965
$0.75


0.95

1.26
0.99


0.10
0.80


0.85
0.46

0.93
1.51
1.71
1.51
1966
$
0.25
0.90
0.85


0.48



0.77


0.90

0.89
0.79
1.50
1.90
1.48
1967
$


0.64


0.98



0.91


0.69


0.79
1.49

1.47
*(a) Less than $10,000

-------
      The overriding force which causes this failing is the "readiness
to proceed" concept.  It must be concluded that in most instances
Federal construction grants have been awarded on a "readiness/willing-
ness to proceed11 basis, and apparently no systematic effort has been
made to maximize benefits from assisting in the construction of
municipal waste treatment facilities.

      On the other  hand, it is equally true construction grant funds
should not be approved and set aside for a community to use whenever
it decided it was ready to proceed.  From the agency's point of view,
the.optimum condition requires that the monies be put to use as
quickly as possible to assist in solving or bringing under control
particularly critical pollution problems not necessarily within one
State but perhaps over a wider area.
                                  119

-------
                 PUBLIC TREATMENT OF  INDUSTRIAL WASTE


                             The Situation
     There is increasing  evidence  that a very substantial—if not a
major—portion of  the  recent  pressure on public v/aste treatment capital
originates in the  form of demand for capacity to handle wastes of
industrial origin.

     The dimensions of that demand can not be measured precisely.  The
Municipal Waste Inventory contains an incomplete description of hydrau-
lic loading of the nation's public waste treatment plants; it does
not include an assessment of  the contributions of wastewater by source
of discharge.  There is no inventory of industrial wastes.  The
nearest thing to such  an  accounting is the very generalized set of
estimates for factories using 20 million gallons or more of water a
year that is published at five year intervals by the Census Bureau under
the title Water Use in Manufacturing.

     There are inescapable weaknesses involved in any assessment of the
extent of industrial waste treatment that may be made through use of
public systems on  the  basis of the Bureau of Census data.  The most
recently published information concerns the year 1964.  It is, then,
over five years old; and  the  five  years involved are those in which it
is felt that industrial use of public waste treatment facilities experi-
enced its most marked  increase.  Moreover, Census information involves
only about 10,600  establishments of the more than 300,000 water-using
factories in the United States.  While the surveyed plants account for
more than 97% of estimated water use by manufacturers, it is suspected
that the small plants  that are excluded have been the ones which his-
torically have been most  apt  to use municipal facilities.  The estimated
434 billion gallons of water  used  by such small plants in 1964 must, in
large part, have been  discharged to public sewers and may be thought
to account for an  indeterminate portion of the 100 gallons per-capita
per day that is often  assumed to be the normal municipal loading rate
to waste treatment plants.

     A hazy assessment of the over-all impact of industrial loadings
on municipal systems is,  however,  possible.  We can establish—imper-
fectly, and lacking detail—that factories and people make approximately
equal demands on public facilities for transmitting and treating liquid
wastes.
                                  121

-------
     Water Use in Manufacturing, with  Its aggregate estimates of water
use by the largest  industrial users, Is the source of Table 48 that pre-
sents the regional  distribution of major water-using manufacturers'
discharges to public  sewers,  as they are accounted for in that document
for 1964.  (The  regions are the blocks of States used in discussion of
locational influences on  cost:  See Figure 2.)

     The table indicates  that twenty percent or more of the water that
passed through public sewers  in 1964 was the discharge of major manu-
facturing plants.   One of the problems in comparing aggregate domestic
and industrial discharges is  the  basic uncertainty that exists with
regard to per-capita  domestic waste discharges.  While one hundred
gallons  per-capita  per day is a common rule of thumb, the number is
conceded to  include some  sort of  "normal" industrial-commercial com-
ponent.  Measurements of  loadings to individual septic tanks, houseboat
discharges,  and  largely residential communities suggest that per-capita
domestic loadings  tend to be  well  below the accepted 100 gallons,
falling  in a range  of roughly 45  to 65 gallons.  To accommodate both
traditional  sizing  standards  and  more  recent measurements, the compari-
son of municipal and major manufacturers' discharges to public sewers
was calculated  on  the basis of  a  municipal loading of both 100 and 65
gallons  per  capita  per day.

      The table  does not,  however, sufficiently describe the  impact of
 Industrial wastes  on municipal  treatment requirements.  Annual volume
of wastewater discharged to sewers fails to  reflect significant aspects
of waste treatment, notably timing and concentrations.

      Domestic waste loadings tend to  vary on  an  hourly basis, with
morning  and  early evening peaks.   There  is also  a weekly bias—that  is
 lessening  over time—imparted by  the  tradition of Monday washdays.
 But,  over the course of a year, loadings are homogenous for  most com-
munities.   Some industrial discharges, on  the other hand,  have
 pronounced cyclical patterns.  Seasonal  operations occur in  many indus-
 trial sectors and the five day work week is  still the standard for
 industry.   Significant in this  regard is  the fact that food  processing,
which accounted for a quarter of estimated industrial discharges to
 public sewers in 1964, is highly seasonal  in at  least some of  its  forms.

      Because waste treatment plant design  is scaled of necessity to
 daily peak loading rates rather than average annual  loadings,  the  effect
 of industrial  operating fluctuations is  to place a multiplier  upon capa-
 city requirements.

      The higher average materials concentrations of industrial wastes
 also  serves  to move municipal costs away from the level  indicated  by
 average annual  hydraulic volume.   Industrial waste concentrations  tend
 to vary widely.   A study by FMPCA of seventy-seven municipal waste treat-
ment  plants  that recorded industrial  waste data revealed influent
concentrations that ranged from 9400 milligrams of standard  biochemical
oxygen demand (BOOs) per liter of water down to 20 mg/1.   The mean value


                                   122

-------
                                               Table 48
                                       Pattern of Waste Discharges
                                   To Public Sewers By Manufacturing
                            Plants Using 20 Million Gallons Or More In 1964
Region
New England
Northeast
Oh1o-Tenn.
Great Lakes
Middle Atlantic
Southeast
Gulf
Plains
Southwest
Pacific Coast
Total
Discharges Percent
Billion Gallons To Public
Total To Public Sewers Sewers
488
2439
2129
2483
986
851
2350
291
96
1452
13,56ol/
49
204
172
297
39
32
28
64
22
151
10581/
10.1
8.4
8.1
12.0
4.0
3.8
1.2
22.0
22.9
10.4
7.8
For Comparison Domestic
Wastes Billion Gallons
@65G/Cap1ta (3100G/Capita
157
653
243
514
158
181
260
185
89
356
2796
242
1004
374
790
243
279
400
285
137
547
4301
Manufactu
Discharge
Percent o
24-17
24-17
41-32
37-27
20-14
15-10
10-7
26-18
20-14
30-22
27-20
—   Exceeds reported U.
    of State figures.
                        S. total, apparently due to effects of rounding in the Census Bureau's reporting

-------
(weighted for volume) of the industrial influents to the seventy-seven
treatment plants was 535 mg/l--more than two and a half times that of
domestic wastes; and the median value was 350 mg/1.  Cost modifying
effects of the diffuse  concentration pattern is by no means uniform.
Higher concentrations,  to the extent that the nutrient balance of the
influent is proper, accelerate biological productivity of the life
forms that accomplish the treatment effect.  In such cases, a given
level of efficiency is  obtained with a reduction in time of detention,
and  a consequent easing of  costs.  Higher or lower concentrations may
require longer detention, recirculation or dilution, thus jacking
capital requirements upward.

      It is, of course,  impossible  to accurately assess the impact of
these conditions on physical capital, but the total estimated industrial
discharge to  public sewers  in 1964 can be weighted by aoprooriate adjust-
ment factors  to give a  generalized view of the relative demands on
facilities posed by domestic and industrial wastes, both in terms of
hydraulic loading  and of biochemical oxygen demand.  Such adjustment
suggests  that, on  the basis of an  indicated 11 billion gallons a day
of actively utilized waste  treatment capacity, almost 40? was taken up
by industrial wastes.   !_/   When the focus shifts from volume of water
to gross  volume of oxynen demanding materials, industrial wastes treated
in municipal  plants accounted for  53/£ to 63^ of the total. 2/
 I/  The statement assumes 1)  a  260  day  average ooprating year for
 Tactories 2)  65 gallons oer capita  per  day of municioal waste loadings,
 3) availibility of treatment  capacity to  sewered industrial wastes in
 the same proportion as to sewered domestic wastes, 4) half of the wastes
 of minor manufacturing plants discharged  to oublic sewers.  Percentage
 industrial  utilization was computed:

                 I =      C+D
                        C+D+ABE

      Where
          A = sewered population of United  States  (118.5 million)
          B = daily per-capita waste discharge  (65 gallons)
          C = annual  sewered wasteflow of major manufacturing  plants
                               (1058 billion  gallons)
          D = annual  sewered wasteflow of minor manufacturing  plants
                              (50% of 434 billion  gallons)
          E = average number of manufacturing days per year  (260  days).

 2/  The statement rests on a comparison of "normal"  domestic  waste
 strength of 1/6 pound of BOD5 oer person oer day  and normal water dis-
 charge of 65 gallons per person oer day with industrial  concentrations
 of 350 mg/1 of 800$ (median for the seventy-seven communities measuring
 industrial waste strength) to 535 mg/1 of  BODs (average  for the  77
 communities.
                                   124

-------
                                                        TARLE 49

                                               Distribution of Industrial
                                             Loadings to a Sample Group of
                                           Municipal  Sewage Treatment Plants
              BOD5
         Concentration
         of Industrial
         Influent, mg/1
                  No.  of
                  Plants
            Hydraulic
            Total  Volume
            1n Million
            Gals./Day
             Percent
             of Total
             Volume
              Total Pounds
              BODs of
              Industrial
              Influents
               Percent
               of Total
               BOD5 to
               Plant
ro
in
 100 or less
 101-200
 201-300
 301-400
 401-500
 601-700
 701-800
 801-900
 901-1300
1501-1900
2100-3000
   4000
   9000
 7
13
 8
 9
 7
 6
 4
 4
 6
 4
 7
 1
 1
                                             6.70
                                            28.36
05
61
37
88
                                             6.27
                                             2.76
                                            10.27
                                              .40
                                              .04
                                              .01
                                              .01
 8.1
34.3
 7.3
 5.6
11.3
 2.3
 7.6
 3.3
12.4
 5.3
 2.5
 0.1
 0.1
 2,770
39,190
12,700
13,590
33,510
10,530
38,340
19,550
91,310
63,830
41,460
   670
 1,560
 0.7
10.5
 3.4
 3.6
 9.0
 2.8
10.3
 5.2
24.4
17.
11
 0.
                                                  1
                                                 .1
                                                 ,2
                                                0.4
          TOTAL
                   77
               82.73
                              374,010

-------
     Even in 1964,  then,  industrial waste discharges appear to have
been a significant,  if  not  a preponderant, source of demand for munici-
pal waste treatment  capacity.  The 1968 municipal waste inventory pro-
vides enough information  on plant size and hydraulic loadings to lead
to the inference  that   the  volume of  industrial loadings has increased
substantially.  Total hydraulic  loadings of the municipal waste treat-
ment system may be  calculated  to have increased to something over 15
billion gallons a day,  on the  basis of average daily flows.  Of that
total, 37% to  59% (the  spread  is due  to the 65 to 100 gallons per/capita
day standards  used  to assess domestic loadings) may be estimated, on the
basis of connected  populations,  to be due to industrial influents.

     The details  of the information on which that assessment is based
are presented  graphically in Figure 6.  The figure contrasts the median
size of municipal waste treatment plants according to community popu-
lation with the median  hydraulic loading in each population size group.

     On the basis of the  observed relationships, it seems clear that
per-capita volume of sewage rises  with size of community population.
The a priori assumption made here is that the reason for the condition
is industrial  wastes, and the  rising availability of factories to
discharge their wastes  in larger communities.  The assumption fits
industrial location  probabilities, and such limited specific informa-
tion as we possess with respect  to occurrence of industrial use of
municipal systems.
                           Policy Aspects

     There can be no question that any effort at water pollution con-
trol that does not  accept as a minimum condition the treatment of
industrial wastes will be a failure.  The estimated volume of oxygen
demanding materials discharged from manufacturing plants amounts to
three times that of sewered sanitary wastes—before treatment in each
case; and the estimated volume of solids discharged from manufacturing
plants is roughly two and a half times that of sanitary sewage, again
before treatment.  Moreover, the volume of industrial v/aste is growing
several times as fast as that of sanitary sewage as a result of growing
per capita output of goods, progressively declining raw materials con-
centrations, and progressively increasing degrees of orocessing per
unit of product.

     On the broadest quantitative levels, then, control of industrial
wastes assumes a critical position for pollution control programs.  A
community that maintains effective treatment of its sanitary sewage can
still be a polluter if industrial waste discharges from its borders are
uncontrolled. In the interest of effective community action, both sewage
and industrial wastes must be dealt with in the conduct of local pol-
lution control programs. Many communities—probably not a majority,
                                 126

-------
ro
Community
Population
Cateqory

  under-500
    500-999
  1,000-2499
  2,500-4999
  5,000-9999
 10,000-24,999
 25,000-49,999
 50,000-99,999
100,000-249,999
250,000-500,000
over 500,000
                                                    TABLL 50
                                        Relative Domestic and  Industrial
                              Loadinn of Municipal Waste Treatment Plants  in
1400
1600
2400
1300
1000
 800
 300
 160
  85
  28
  24
                                                              Million Gallons  Per  Day
Gross
Indicated
Loading
64.0
156.0
588.0
682.5
1050.0
2010.0
1637.5
2040.0
2677.5
2100.0
2700.0
Domestic

3 100 G/C/D
19. 0
120.0
420.0
487.5
750.0
1400.0
1125.0
1200.0
1487.5
1050.0
1800.0
Comnonont

0 65 G/C/D
32.0
78.0
273.0
317.0
487.5
910.0
731.0
780.0
967.0
682.5
1170.0
Industrial

Remainder
5.0- 2.0
36.0- 78.0
168.0- 315.0
195.0- 366.0
300.0- 562.5
610.0-1100.0
562.5- 956.2
840.Q-1260.0
1190.0-1710.0
1050.0-1417.5
900.0-1530.0
                                                23-50
                                                23-50
                                                29-54
                                                29-54
                                                29-54
                                                30-55
                                                33-57
                                                41-62
                                                44-64
                                                50-68
                                                33-57
             TOTAL
                        9100
         15,756.0
9890.0
6430.0
5870.0-9325.0
37-59

-------
                        Figure 6
 II

 '

 1.5
 1.4
 1.3
 !;
 ••
 1.0
 0.9
 0.8
 0.7
0.6
05
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
 0
          RELATIVE DOMESTIC AND
              INDUSTRIAL LOADING
         PUBLIC  WASTE TREATMENT
                     PLANTS
  Median Capacity Available
    Median  Loading Rate
Indicated  Industrial  Utilization
       of Capacity
          normal Municipal Loading
    Normal Industrial Loading Component
        Domestic Loading  Requirement
       05   1.0  2.5  50   10.0 25.0  50.0  100.0  250.0 500.0
               SIZE OF PLACE  (OOO'S)
                         128

-------
for the simple reason that factories tend to be concentrated—have
accepted the simple technique of treating all, or most, of the wastes
occurring within their jurisdiction, v/ithout regard to its source.

     That practice, taken for granted for many years in the case of
inner city fabricating plants and aoplauded as a progressive innovation
when extension to major peripheral or waterside factories was initiated
on a large scale, has recently come under attack on grounds of equity
or propriety.  Antagonists have questioned the suitability of applying
public resources and public funds to the solution of the problems of
profit making industries.  In particular, the General Accounting Office,
in a preliminary report to the Congress on the administration of Federal
waste treatment plant construction grants, cast doubt on the validity
of the practice of extending Federal assistance on the basis of total
construction cost rather than restricting the scope of Federal assis-
tance to capacity intended to serve domestic users only.  (It is,
perhaps, significant that the GAO's final report to the Congress con-
tained almost no mention of the subject, and had no recommendations with
regard to the matter.  Established usage, economy and efficiency may
have been such persuasive arguments for current Federal assistance
practice in this regard as to change the reviewers' first reactions—or
they may simply have despaired of developing procedures for resolving
the enormous problems of definition involved in determining what  is in
fact a "municipal" waste source and what is properly  industrial.)

     The estimates of investment  need  presented earlier in this  study
presume—through application of  sizing standards and projections of
rate of  increase in  loadings—continuation of  current tendencies  toward
broader  public responsibility for industrial waste  treatment.  As has
been noted,  industrial sources presently sustain a  rough  parity^with
domestic and commercial sources in  demand on oublic waste  handling
sources, and maintenance of  trends  in  full  force today will  soon  give
factory  wastes a predominant  position.   Industrial  needs,  then^must be
considered  to be a central matter in  determining investment  policy.
The  remaining portion of this section  of our  study  attemnts  to qualify
the  economic impacts of public  treatment of  industrial wastes  in terms
of effectiveness  (or contributions  to  water pollution control),  effi-
ciency  (approach to  maximum  output  derived  from anticipated  resource
inputs), equity,  in  its  economic  sense of  assessing costs  on  the basis
of benefits received and/or  damages  incurred,  and  of  technical  and
institutional practicability.

Effectiveness

      Public treatment  of industrial  wastes  is  effective in insuring the
utility of  the  treatment  of sanitary wastes,  since it guarantees that
the  results of  treatment for the domestic  pooulation will  not be nulli-
fied by the effects  of untreated industrial  wastes.  It is effective,
too,  in that it locates  resoonsibility for the operation and mainten-
ance of the local  waste handling activity within  a single authority
with a clearly  defined responsibility for the operation and maintenance


                                   129

-------
of the local waste handling activity that is assigned to a group of
professional operators.   In substance, it puts the municipal or other
public agency into a public utility status with resoect to an industry
segment or group of factories—a posture not afall unlike one that
it normally accents on behalf of a group of residential and commercial
customers, and often for  other public jurisdictions or agencies as well.

     An element that enters strongly into consideration of the effec-
tiveness of that relationship, but one which is difficult to quantify,
is the weakness of industry's incentives to treat wastes adequately.
Waste treatment is a collateral and profitless activity from the stand-
point of the firm.  Subjective though it may be, the general opinion of
professionals in the field of water oollution control is that factory
management often views waste treatment as an imposed responsibility that
may most conveniently be  discharged for form's sake by constructing a
facility—which may then  be operated very indifferently.  This opinion
assumes a critical importance, in view of the industrial tendency to
reject capital intensive  waste treatment methods, even where a con-
siderable increase in ooerating costs is incurred thereby.  (The low
capital, high operating cost formula is rational from the standpoint of
the firm, both because it frees capital for alternative and profitable
applications, and because of the quite separate effects of corporate
tax provision for operating expenses and capital depreciation.)  Given
that set.of conditions, there is relative assurance of effective waste
treatment where industrial wastes are channeled through a public system.
Responsibility is passed  to an instrumentality with a strongly developed
set of incentives to operate and maintain the system in an acceptable
fashion.  Even where the  cost to industry is equal on an annual basis,
it has an incentive to adopt the use of public facilities, both because
operational problems are  removed from its purview and because the full
amount of any sewer charge becomes a tax deductible expense in the year
incurred, without the interposition of deferred depreciation requirements

Efficiency

     That is efficient in an economic sense which increases the output
of products from a given  input of resources.  Efficiency, then, is a
relative and not an absolute test.  But if the task of the public admin-
istrator is to maximize the satisfactions available from the resources
available to him, efficiency must always be a prime goal.

     There is no question that in a majority of cases public treatment
of industrial wastes is more efficient than separate treatment of muni-
cipal and industrial wastes, in that it commonly costs less per gallon
of water processed or per unit of pollutant removed to treat waste
from several sources at a single point.

     There are two reasons for the cost advantage.  On the one hand,
economies of scale are attained by construction and utilization of
larger plants that are required when a number of independent waste
                                  130

-------
sources are collected  at  one  point  for  treatment:  on the other,
staging capabilities and  complementary  characteristics of sewage and
industrial wastes often permit  operational economies.

     The order of magnitude in  which  economies of scale occur is
indicated in Table  51  which lists cost  to size relationships for the
principal waste  treatment processes.  Though  the cost of the incremental
unit placed into operation varies according to the treatment process
employed, the savings  that accrue through consolidation and use of
larger plants are substantial in every  case.

     Perhaps the principle may  best be  presented through use of an
example.  Consider  the situation of a community that develops 10 million
gallons a day of liquid wastes  in some  combination of savage and indus-
trial discharges and—for the sake  of illustration—assume that it is
physically convenient  to  provide treatment 1) through construction of
ten equally sized plants,  five  operated  by municipality for the use of
residential and  service industry users,  five  operated by individual
factories, 2) through  use of  two equally sized plants, one operated by
the community and the  other by  the  factories  in consortium, 3) through
use of a single  large  plant serving the  needs of all waste producers in
the community.  Assuming  a twenty-five year useful life of plant, a
five percent rate of interest and serial amortization in each case, and
equal transmission  costs,  the alternative solutions would entail dif-
ferential costs on  the order  of those presented in Figure 7.

     Over the life  of  the system, average annual costs would amount to
about $584,000 in the  case of the ten plant solution, $451,000 in the
case of the two plants, and $332,000  for the  single plant solution.
Obviously, it is to the benefit of  the  community and its residents to
utilize the single  plant  solution—if the consequent cost savings can
be shared equitably among  the various categories of waste producers.

     Not so obvious, but  equally true,  is the fact that it is to the
benefit of the national economy to  seek  the single plant kind of solu-
tion whenever it is possible.   By doing  so, the Nation frees for other
purposes resources  that might otherwise  be utilized for waste treatment.

     In practice, scale economies may in many—perhaps a majority—of
cases be supplemented  by  operational  economies derived from the char-
acteristics of wastes  from disparate  sources.  Complementary daily flow
cycles of manufacturing and of  domestic  activities can be utilized to
reduce demands for  peaking capacity.  Many industrial wastes are
deficient in nitrogen  and/or  phosphorus  that  are required to sustain
effective bacterial action in the treatment process.  Such wastes must
be fertilized by the addition of those nutrients.  Sewage, on the other
hand, characteristically  contains both nitrogen and phosphorus in excess
of bacterial needs.  By combining sewage and  industrial wastes, the
nutrient deficiency characteristic  of the latter may be supplied, with
an absolute reduction  and  often elimination of need for chemical addi-
tives.   And because nitrogen  and phosphorus residuals of sewage


                                 131

-------
                                                      TABLE 51
                                     Generalized Cost To Size Relationships of
                                          Basic Waste Treatment  Processes
                PROCESS
Million Halions Per Day Capacity
CO
ro


Primary
Primary, Separate Sludge Digestion
Activated Sludge
Trickling Filter
Lagoons
•
11.
6.
Ol_
7
2
.10 J[
Construction Cos
58.7
85.2
70.8
101.8
23.4
Annual Operating
Primary
Primary,
Activated
Trickling
Lagoons
*Source:
**Source:
Separate, Sludge Digestion
Sludge
Filter
Modern Sewage Treatment Plants,
Treatment Plant Cost Index for
0.
How
1
Much
4.5
5.5
6.3
5.1
0.6
Do They
308
305
417
288
88
i£
t, $1000
.6
.1
.3
.9
.0
's
1,
1,
2,
1,
& Maintenance Charges
19
20
31
18
3
.7
.6
.3
.3
.0

10
*
247
092
458
374
330
i2
.7
.2
.9
.4
.3
TOO
6,559
3,084
14,487
5,045
1,080
JJ
.0
.0
.6
.2
.0
, $1000's**
172
83
.3
.3


Cost and Sewage
June 1969
R, L. Michels, et al "Operation and Maintenance of Municipal Waste
Treatment Plants," Journal of the Water Pollution Control Federation
»




                March 1969.  1962-64 dollars raised to 1968-69 conditions by use of BLS
                Craftsmen's median earning, 1968 * craftsmen's median earnings, 1963 X
                table value

-------
   .^  1.000,000

CD  OJ
LT5 Q-
   (-=3
         100,000

          10,000
       10  plants

        2  plants

        1  plants
           Un'tCn
                                                                 10 Plants
                                   ($1,000,0001
                                    :ffSu!3ECC;:°
                                              2 Plants
                                                                             -a

                                                                             CD
                                                                                                                       OO
                                                                                                                       C-D
                                                                                          Plant
                                    100,000                 1,000,000

                                              Capacity in Gallons  Per Day
                                                 10,000,000
Construction
   Cost

$4,200,000

$3,200,000

$2,500,000
  Interest
   Charges

$2,600,000

$2,000,000

$1,500,000

Fiqure 7
25 Years
Operation

$7,800,000

$6,000,000

$4,300,000
                                                                                                              CT
                                                                                                                       CD
                                                                                                                  CO
                                                                                                                         i
                                                                                                                           oo
                                                                             C/D
 Lifetime
 _Costs_

$14,600,000

$11,300,000

$ 8,300,000

-------
treatment are in themselves a serious source of pollution, the incre-
mental reduction of  those  nutrients  in the ultimate discharge that
occurs when they are incorporated  in sludges derived from the industrial
wastes means that  the waste treatment may often be more complete and
effective than conventional secondary sewage treatment.  A final source
of potential economy and enhanced  effectiveness should be noted.  The
temperature of industrial  wastes is  often higher than the sewage.  In
those cases where  the volume  and temperature of wastes from industrial
sources  is sufficient to increase  meaningfully the temperature of the
total volume of wastes  being  treated, the effect is to accelerate the
life processes of  the bacteria  that  effect the decomposition processes.
That metabolic acceleration produces an  efficiency increment, in that
a given  degree of  waste stabilization can be attained with a reduction
in detention time—and  thus a reduction  in capacity requirements—or
a higher degree of reduction  is achieved where there is no change in
the period of detention.

      It  should  be  noted that  the  indicated operational efficiencies are
quite apart  from,  and additional to, those derived from scale economies.
Because  the  practical effect  of the  two  biochemical mechanisms—higher-
average  temperature  effects and takeup of  sewage nutrients by industrial
sludges—is  more complete  waste treatment, absolute pollution abatement
benefits as  well as  relative  cost  reductions are apt to flow from muni-
cipal-industrial joint  waste  treatment arrangements.

Technical  &  Institutional  Practicability

      It  is  probable, as indicated  earlier,  that  industrial wastes are
currently  the  major  source of loadings discharged  into public waste
treatment  plants.   (The statement  presumes  application of a correct
definition  of  "industry,"  but it may well  be true  even if the idiomatic
substitution of "industry" for  "factory" is made).  The textbook stan-
dard  that  dates  back to the 1920's specifies that  per-capita waste
production  is  100  gallons  per day; but even  traditional sizing  standards
reflect  some assumption of the  existence of  a  "normal" industrial
requirement  above  the capacity  that must be  installed to  handle produc-
tion  of  domestic  sewage.   In  fact, however,  100  gallons per capita per
day fails  completely to measure the inflow to  modern sewage treatment
plants.  Hydraulic demand  rises consistently with  community size; and
in even  the  smallest size  class,  the median  loading level is 110 gallons
per capita.per day.

Some  authorities  have attempted to explain  a higher than  normal level
of loadings  on  the basis of increased  per capita use of water that is
presumed to  have accompanied  rising  living  standards.  There is prob-
ably  validity  in the observation;  but  it cannot  be used to upset the
conclusion  that  public  treatment of  industrial wastes accounts  for
more  than  half of  capacity utilization  in  present  day waste treatment
plants.  Both  the  fact  that relatively recent  studies are responsible
                                   134

-------
for the assessment of residential sewage production of 40-65 gallons
per capita per day and the fact that one in four sewage treatment plants
presently handles 75 gallons per capita per day or less—with no appre-
ciable increase in incidence of reported overloading among such plants-
tends to support the statement that industry and not rising individual
use of water is responsible for most of the incremental need for public
waste treatment plants.

     Thus, there is nothing either novel or exciting about the practice
of accepting industrial wastes in municipal treatment plants.  It is
simply a continuation of  established practice.  As cities have instal-
led sewers, they have customarily attached commercial and service
establishments to the sewer network, and in many cases manufacturing
establishments were connected  as well.  When, under the pressure of
events, the sewered waste streams came  to be collected and passed
through a v/aste treatment plant, all recipients of the sewer service
became customers of the  treatment service.  In point of fact, there is
little option for many firms.  Location may constrain  any establishment
located within a city to  utilize public sewers to  carry away its liquid
wastes.

     What  is significant  is  the  fact that  a definite  change  in the
composition of industries using  public  facilities  has  occurred.  Until
fairly  recently factories that made  heavy  use  of water in  their  pro-
cessing tended to  take  advantage of  waterside  locations to  discharge
wastes  directly,  rather  than through  the  intermediary of  public  sewers.
Where  the  small plant  located within  the  built-up  area of the  city
customarily used  the  sewer,  the  large  plant  located  on the periphery
discharged independently.  But the situation  has  been changing  radically
with  the  imposition of more  stringent  and more broadly applied  pollution
abatement  requirements.   With increasing  prevalence, Jarge water-using,
peripherally  located  factories have  attempted  to  satisfy  publicly
imposed operating  demands through  the use of public facilities.

      Host of  the  wastes of the group of food processing industries that
receive treatment get it in public waste treatment plants.  It is
becoming  more and more common for paper mills, and even pulp mills, to
discharge wastes  into public sewers.   Chemical, pharmaceutical,  plastics,
 textile  and  rubber plants wastes have been successfully incorporated
 into public treatment systems.  In six of eleven major manufacturing
 sectors!  the  prevalence of treatment through public systems in 1964
 equalled  or exceeded prevalence of treatment in industry-operated
 plants.  In spite of the fact that the three manufacturing sectors that
 make most abundant use of process water (primary metals, chemicals and
 allied products, and paper and allied  products) are often precluded
 from use of pub lie treatment  facilities by reason of discharge volume
 or waste characteristics, a fourth of  the gross volume of factory waste
 ?nVt was treated passed  through public facilities in that year.
                                   135

-------
(See Table 52.)  The proportion is probably greater today.  And it is
safe to assume that in almost all cases, waste treatment provided to
commercial and service industries depends upon use of public facilities,

                               TABLE 52

                        Relative Prevalence of
             Industry-Provided and Publicly-Provided Waste
             Treatment by Major Manufacturing Sector, 1964
                                   PERCENT OF WASTE TREATED
                                BY INDUSTRY  BY PUBLIC SOURCES

Food & Kindred Pdts.                34.9          65.1
Textile Mill Pdts.                  38.4          61.6
Paper 5 Allied Pdts.                91.4           8.6
Chemical & Allied Pdts.             88.0          12.0
Petroleum & Coal                    90.9           9.1
Rubber & Plastics                   50.0          50.0
Primary Metals                      95.8           4.2
Machinery                           20.6          79.4
Electrical Machinery                16.5          83.5
Transportation Eqpt.                34.0          66.0
Other Mfg.                          58.9          41.1
All Mfg.                            75.2          24.8


     Generally speaking, there are no technological impediments to
common use of treatment facilities by manufacturers and by households.
The treatment processes are basic and simple, applicable to most kinds
of waste.  There are some wastes that require processing other than, or
additional to, the screening, sedimentation, flotation and the biochem-
ical stabilization employed in conventional municipal waste treatment
systems.  In such cases, industry must either provide pretreatment
measures or supply its own treatment facilities.

     A variety of institutional and procedural practices have been
developed to extend treatment to factory wastes.  The nature of the
arrangement between public agency and factory tends to be decided on
a local level, though some regionally consistent trends may be noted
with respect to financing treatment.

     With respect to physical facilities, the common method is to treat
both sewage and industrial wastes in a single plant in order to attain
the economies of scale and complementarities available from the practice.
On many occasions, the pressure on capacity imposed by such an arrange-
ment has created a need for major plant expansion or even plant
replacement; and there can be little doubt that the availability of
Federal
                                  136

-------
construction grants has made such arrangements far more attractive to
industry.  It is unusual, but the practice of providing separate
facilities for the use of industrial customers, or even a single custo-
mer, is not unknown.  Though owned and operated by a public agency,
such a facility must be regarded as an extension of the factory in
point of fact.  Such arrangements have been viewed as a subterfuge to
obtain public funds for the use of a private interest.  The generali-
zation is, perhaps, too sweeping.  Each situation should properly be
reviewed in the context of its financing and its place in the total
public system.  But there can be no question that the few arrangements
of this sort—no more than half a dozen were uncovered in a superficial
review of Federal grant awards—are responsible for much of the opposi-
tion that has been raised to providing Federal grants for construction
of the portion of a treatment facility that will be used to treat
industrial wastes.

     Financial mechanisms that have been applied to fund the capacity
requirements associated with wider public  treatment of industrial wastes
probably have a large effect on the favor  or disfavor with which the
practice is generally evaluated.  An  increasingly favored method of
obtaining revenues is the use of the  sewer service charge.  Its pre-
valence has grown with  expansion of public treatment of factory wastes;
and the existence of some very complex charge  formulae based on volume,
strength, and characteristics of wastes argues strongly that industrial
wastes, rather than domestic swage with its homogenous character, is
a factor contributing to the extension of  sewer charge systems.  User
charges are not, however, universal.   In some  cases, particularly  in
the Northeastern States, there is  a tendency to continue to rely on
general taxation to finance treatment works.   It is often  the  case
that where user charges  exist they  tend to be  scaled to provide for
plant and sewer operation and maintenance, with general taxes  often
covering capital costs—the typically higher coupon rate of local  reve-
nue bonds may account in part for  this.  Where capital and debt
servicing charges  are built  into the  scale of  user fees, the practice
is  to establish them  at rates  that cover only  local participation  in
the investment.   (Cases may exist  where  the amount of  Federal  assist-
ance  is  also  charged  back  to  users,  but  we are unaware of them.)


    User charges,  general  taxes,  Federal  and  State grants  are  the
usual means  to  finance  and  service the elements  of  industrial  waste
treatment that  use public  facilities, but  specialized  kinds of finan-
cial  relationships  have also  been  developed  on the  local  level.   There
have  been instances  where  the firms that  propose to  share  in the  use  of
a municipal  treatment system have  advanced a  proportion  of the funds
required for construction,  have contributed  land for the purpose,  or
have  purchased  the bonds issued to finance construction.   Nor  is  factory
construction of a  plant in which capacity is  provided for an adjoining
communitv unknown,  though  the few such situations  that come to mind ante-
date  availability of Federal  assistance for plant construction.


                                  137

-------
     Operational procedures would seem, on the basis of the information
that is available, to have involved no undue prpblems.  Contrary to the
generally held engineering opinion of a decade ago, when communities
were cautioned against the operating problems that industrial v/astes
would impose, treatment seems generally to take place with little or no
more difficulties as the proportion of industrial wastes in the influent
has increased.  It would seem that discharge conditions are usually
stipulated with some precision  in order to forestall malfunctions, and
that factories generally install the equipment and procedures necessary
to meet those requirements.

     Operational failures are not unknown, however; and when they occur,
they may be spectacular; as  in  the case of the Michigan plant where
bacterial action was short-circuited by a change in the characteristics
of a paper mill's discharge, so that sludge drying beds emitted powerful
odors of putrefaction; or the case of the Ohio waste treatment plant
that literally  burned  down,  presumably as the result of ignition of an
accidentally discharged and  volatile industrial waste.

     Review of  the  literature provides few serious examples of opera-
tional  failures.  More common is the sort of damage that results from
inadequate design applications  or loss of an industrial waste source.
Where  a treatment plant  is designed in substantial part to accommodate
the wastes of  a factory, and that factory stops  its operation, a signi-
ficant loss of  sunk capital  is  inescapable.  Similarly, the application
of sewer service charges that embody incentives  to reduce waste dis-
charges through in-plant modifications has on occasion proved too
successful.   Factories have  succeeded in reducing the volume or strength
of their discharges to the point that a significant portion of the
capacity of the treatment plant is not utilized, with the result that
system users  find themselves in the unfortunate  position of paying for
a good deal of unnecessary capacity.

Equity

      It would  seem  that  the  central difficulty that exists with respect
to the practice of  treating  industrial wastes in public systems is the
ethical  problem of  the propriety of supplying out of  public  facilities
and public funds a  service  to assist a private interest.  The problem
becomes particularly pointed when  Federal  construction grants are  in-
volved, for the simple reason that the Congress  has evinced  a disin-
clination  to  provide general subsidies for industrial waste  treatment
purposes.

     Yet there  is  something  specious about the ethical question and
the terms  in which  it is  phrased.  The distinction  between a municipal
waste  and  an  industrial  waste is an artificial one, wholly dependent on
definition.  The prevailing  pattern of opinion has  been to accept  all
commercial and service industries  as legitimate  contributors to the
municipal waste streams,  and even  to accept  small  factories  or  "dry
process" industries as the  "normal  industrial component" of  "municipal"

                                   138

-------
wastes.  Where, then, does one draw the line?  Commercial laundries  and
restaurants nay logically be considered to be only extensions of domes-
tic activities, as may hotels and motels.  But v;hat of the grocery store
and the department store?  Do warehouses and marshalling yards generate
municioal wastes or  industrial wastes?  What about the airport, the
shopping center, the industrial park?

     These questions may be valid, but they must be admitted to be
somewhat beside the  point.  The real distinction involved is not one
of source, but of relative magnitude.  Certain manufacturing industries
characterized by very large plants and marked use of water per unit of
output are generally accepted to be the exclusive source of "industrial"
v/aste.  Not the fact that the waste comes from a factory, but that the
amount of v/aste approaches or exceeds the amount generated by the
population dependent on that factory causes its discharge to be so
distinguished.  It is in the case where incremental costs imposed by
the necessity to treat the industrial wastes are significant that the
equity question is posed.

     The distinction on the basis of relative magnitude may well be a
valid one.  The damages occasioned by the major water-using industries
are generally recognized to exceed those of all other waste-discharging
sources.  Similarly, the incremental abatement costs posed by factories
in such industries are so much  greater than the incremental cost of
providing for the retail establishment or the dry process industry,
that  it would appear that  the general public's interest  is affected in
a significantly different manner when it is asked to bear that cost.
Conversely, the benefits—in  terms of potential water quality enhance-
ment—are also disproportionately great vfhen such a factory's wastes
receive treatment.   Moreover, the water quality benefit  is received by
the oublic at large. There would seem, then, to be considerable logic
in support of Federal or State  grants in such a situation.

      Nor is the equity question a simple matter of the  apparent
injustice of using public  funds to  remove  the burden of  waste treatment
from  a private  interest  to whom that  burden will represent a  significant
incremental cost.  If Federal  grants were  to be withheld or  reduced to
certain communities  that  treat  a  significant amount of  industrial wastes,
then  the community that  takes  a broad view  of its  environmental protec-
tion  responsibilities—seeking  in  an  enlightened fashion to  ensure
their effectiveness  and  efficiency  over  time—will be  penalized, and
the community  that takes  the  narrow  view of its  responsibilities will
achieve a relative advantage.   Cities generally would  be penalized  by
such  a policy,  since a  large  portion  of  a  city's waste  come  from in-
dustrial sources  that have no other place  of  discharge  than  the public
savers  while  suburban  settlements  would  receive  an  advantage.  Given
orevailing  income  distribution  in  metropolitan  areas,  the policy would
tend  to  favor  the  relatively  affluent and  hurt  the poor   Moreover,   _
the substantially  arbitrary  distinction  between  municipal  and industrial
                                  139

-------
wastes would tend to produce  inter-sectoral inequities.  Some industrial
sectors would receive the benefit of Federal assistance, others would
be cut off from  it. V

     Finally, it should  be  considered  that there are elements of
regional  discrimination  implicit  in a  policy of limiting grant assis-
tance for public treatment  of industrial wastes.  Not all industries,
but the heavy water-using,  first-stage processors are, as has been
noted, presumed  to  be  the source  of industrial wastes.  To exclude such
waste sources from  Federal  assistance  would be to inflict a distinct
penalty on the  far  West  and on the Southeast where  a disproportionate
share of  industrial  activity is based  on such processing, and where the
propensity to provide  public treatment of  industrial wastes is histor-
ically well  established—in the far West,  at least, the policy antedates
the. Federal  assistance program by at least a decade.

      Potential  inequities  inhere, then, in any public posture that may
be assumed with regard to  broad public treatment of industrial wastes.
The efficiency  and  practicability of the practice are established be-
yond  question.   It  contributes to effectiveness of  pollution abatement
efforts  by establishing  public control  of  wastes from all sources; and
 in heavily  industrialized  urban areas  it is the most practical way to
 achieve  effective water  pollution abatement.  Yet in the  case of certain
 heavy industries,  its  effect is to shift from industry  to the public
 sector an economic  burden  of very sizeable dimensions.

      The essential  question of equity  arises out of the opportunities
 for cost avoidance  that the practice provides manufacturing  industries;
 and objections  to Federal  assistance have  been magnified  by  the exist-
 ence of certain cases  where a local  government's  application for a
 grant amounts to a  thinly masked  effort to obtain public  assistance for
what is  essentially an industrial facility.  Moreover,  the  inequities
 V  This report has been produced in a building that is part of a
 recently constructed complex of office, retail, and residential units,
 populated during the day by persons brought in from more than a fifty
 mile radius, and with a probable waste discharge equal to about one
 sixth of that of the city on whose outskirts it lies.  There is no
 objection to public treatment of the wastes of this paperwork factory
 or to Federal construction grants to provide the plant expansion and
 the transmission  facilities needed to accomplish it.  Yet the effect
 of those grants is to benefit the real estate, construction, retail,
 and financial sectors just as surely as the capacity to handle a
 New England town's tannery wastes benefits the factory owners.
                                   140

-------
that are relatively slight in the context of the Federal program become
enormous on the local level, in the case where general tax revenues
are utilized to construct and operate such a treatment system.

   The equity questions assume a legal coloration when viewed from
the standpoint of Section 8(a) of the Federal Water Pollution Control
Act, which provides that:

     The Secretary [of the Interior] is authorized to make grants
     to any State, municipality, or intermunicipal or interstate
     agency for the construction of necessary treatment works to
     prevent the discharge of untreated or  inadequately treated
     sewage or other waste into any waters.  . .

     The section is specific  in limiting  the availability of  Federal
construction grants to governmental units;  and  the legislative  history
suggests very clearly that there was no Congressional intent  to extend
such grants to industrial  treatment of wastes;  yet the Act provides
that the grants extend to  plants whose purpose  is to  treat not  only
sewage  but  "other wastes," so long as  it  is a governmental agency  that
intends to  construct—and  presumably  to operate—the  works in question.
Nor does the Water  Pollution  Control  Act's  exposition of  the  discretion-
ary powers  and the  responsibilities of the  Secretary  of the  Interior, as
they apply  to  the award  of Federal  Construction Grants, suggest that a
policy  of excluding  communities  for treating  industrial  wastes should
be observed.

     There  is, then,  ambiguity with respect to  the  degree to  which admin
istrative  procedures  should  interpret the intent of  the Congress  with
regard  to municipal  treatment of industrial wastes  in awarding  construc-
tion grants.   There is  also  an obvious disparity between  the  way  in
which municipalities approach their waste treatment responsibilities
and the way in which the Congress viewed those responsibilities when
the act was formulated  over a decade ago.

     Given  the conflicting demands of the situation, it would appear
that  the  Federal  policy should continue to be one that supports effec-
tiveness  and efficiency inherent in the strengthening of local  and
regnal  waste handling programs that are comprehensive  n their reach.
From  the  national  point of view, the fact that availab  ity of Federal
assistance has led to an indirect use of grants by public agencies to
f nance industrial waste treatment works.by inducing «"£«*"•* .J1
 to connect to enlarged municipal system is not in the  east  bad.   It
entirely consistent with the purposes of the Water Pollution Control
Act  si nee it increases the degree of treatment of untreated or inade-
 quately tretei wastes, and adheres to the subsidiary Active of
 contributing to planned regional or metropolitan pollution control
 systems.
                                   141

-------
     Because cost-sharing v/ould seem to lie at the root of the diffi-
culty, remedies might be applied most efficaciously by locally
established requirements to ensure that projects be financed in a fashion
that provides an equitable correspondence between costs occasioned and
payments made.  The simplest and most prevalent procedure to make the
occasion of cost compatible with financial burden is the use of a sewer
service charge scaled to the volume and/or strength of the wastes derived
from each user (or class of users).  Ideally, such a requirement v/ould
be placed by applicants for Federal waste treatment construction grants,
since its overall effect would be to place a price upon waste treatment
that fully reflected the costs of the service,  (Use of general tax
revenues is thought to subsidize inefficiencies by masking costs, and
reducing users' ability to control his costs by limiting his production
of pollutants).  Cut if the only concern is to guard against industrial
exploitation of public resources, charge requirements might be placed
only by systems handling more than 100 gallons per capita per day—or
some other acceptable figure to characterize presumption of a greater
than "normal" industrial loading.

     Admittedly, the imposition of such a requirement v/ould only reduce
the cost-sharing contradictions at the local level.  Federal contribu-
tions to some heavy industry sectors v/ould continue to be greater,
relative to taxes collected, than to others which are less categorized
by liquid waste production.  But to exclude heavy v/aste producers from
participation in Federal programs would only reverse, not eliminate,
the fact of disadvantaged industrial sectors.  The main burden of
Federal relations with industry throughout the nation's history has
been a steady struggle to evolve a pragmatic balance between the public
interest and the characteristic external damages imposed by a given
industry.  There seems to be no reason to depart from that policy in
the case of industries whose characteristic problems include a high
measure of production of water-borne pollutants.  The public interest
would seem best served by including such industries in the enforcement
provisions relating to water pollution, and by providing the States and
municipalities in which they are located a full measure of the assistance
provided to all municipalities for the purpose of pollution abatement.
                                  142

-------
                    REGIONAL WASTE HANDLING SYSTEMS

      The Water Pollution Control Act was framed to favor and support
establishment of regional waste handling systems.  The ostensible
values of regional cooperation and regionally directed orograms underlie
a number of provisions of the Federal Water Pollution Control Act
including ones that   1)  directed  comprehensive river basin studies,
2) required that Federal grants for  construction of waste treatment
works adhere to the conclusions of comprehensive programs developed
under the Act, 3)  provided  a ten  percent incremental grant av/ard for
construction that  is  certified to be included in a metropolitan or
regional olan, and 4) encouraged  interstate compacts.

      It is probably  significant  that the same law that requires that
a community be included  in  a comprehensive plan  augments the amount
of grants to communities that are certified to be included in some
kind of plan.  The fact  that the  incentive postdates the requirement
suggests either that  the rate of  plan development has not matched
expectations, or that there has been some meaningful gap between the
planning process and  its practical results.   To  a certain extent, both
explanations are true descriptions of events.  Planning has been a
painfully slow process.  More relevant  to this discussion, however, is
the fact that river  basin  planning has  failed almost entirely to
produce pollution  control  programs founded on basin systems.

      The argument for  the  river  basin  based  regional system is well
founded.  A regional  system provides a  means  to  adjust  administrative
institutions, capital investment, and  abatement  practices to the over-
riding physical  imperatives of  streamflow, temperature, and water
chemistry—and to  do so in  a manner  that effectuates economies of  scale
and allows selective application  of  effort.   To  obtain  these practical
benefits, it shifts  the focus  of  attention from  the series of specific
sources of pollution, with their  unequal and  interlocking  impacts,  to
the river basin  and  to the physical  conditions  and  chemical  reactions
that  take place  in the stream.   In  concept,  it  is  the most effective
and the least  costly means to  insure water  of given desired  quality.

      But the  river  basin  pollution  control  system  can  not be found in
the United States; and it  shows no  evidence  of coming  into full  scale
existence  in  the near future.   There are, however,  variants  that
flourish with  more or less vigor and public  acceptance.
                                   143

-------
      The problems of implementing regional oollution abatement systems,
then, seem to fall under the heading of practicability.  Their
potential effectiveness, efficiency and equity are unquestioned; but
there seems to be something in the idea that conflicts with American
views of the way that things should be done.  Political realities and
institutionalized procedures collide powerfully with the concent at
a number of olaces; and where a regional solution to a problem has
been adopted after a collision has taken place, regionalism has been
subtly adapted to the needs of pre-existing institutions.  The emphasis
of this discussion, then, will be not upon the theoretical benefits
of regional systems, but upon the difficulties of implementing them,
and on the modifications that theory has experienced as it has been
translated into fact.   If basin systems with all their nresumed
virtues are inconsistent with other values that Americans prefer, it
may be worthwhile to consider the evolutions of the concept that have
been considered to be acceptable, and to devise incentives to organize
in forms that preserve  something of the efficiency and effectiveness
of basin planning, but  that adhere to politically acceptable modes of
action.

      To undertake that kind of comparison, it is necessary to distin-
guish between three characteristic forms of regional organization.

      The  river basin system is the purest form of the regional pollu-
tion control system.  It places all sources of pollutants under a
common regulatory authority with an independent financial base.  The
authority  may undertake remedial measures on the basis of need and
natural  requirements imposed by stream conditions.  The field of
regulatory action is considerably broadened to include measures
other than waste  treatment—streamflow augmentation, waste storage,
waste transmission, in-stream settling, artificial reaeration,
zoning,  assessment of penalties—and the intensity of  treatment
requirements can  be varied to take advantage of natural conditions.

      The  closest approach to this idealized system  is to be found in
Germany, where the Ruhr and Emser Gennosenschaften have for almost
a century  administered  a program of environmental controls that
includes area-wide regulation geared to natural conditions, autonomous
financing  derived from  user and effluent charges, stream  classifica-
tion, and  application of in-stream as well  as  sewerage engineering.
Several  approaches to a basin system have  been made  in the U.S.; but
these efforts have been of the nature of voluntary federations  that
include  an administrative superstructure substantially without
enforcement powers (other than those of the separate constituencies
entering into the agreement) or the resources  to engage in investment
programs.
                                  144

-------
      Note that this discussion is framed in the context of the short
run future.  Historical develooments portend a more distant future in
which the basin-wide authority will have the powers needed not only for
water quality management but total water resource management.  The
Delaware Commission and others constructed in its pattern give insights
into v?hat may evolve;  but  this cannot be expected as a viable mechanism
in most cases in  the period of interest.  How such authorities evolve
will depend upon  Federal DO!icy,  among other factors, and most
significantly on  Federal policy in the water resource field as a
whole rather than in the field of water quality management.  The
Water Resources Council has given attention to this matter, as will
the recently constituted National Water Commission.

     The Metropolitan  Sanitary District is a form of the regional
oollution control  system where the operational base is not the water
body, but the social and economic focus provided by the urban area.
Where the river basin  system has  been neglected, the metropolitan
system is by now  the generally accepted approach to waste handling
in and around major American cities.  Almost without exception, large
cities serve as the nodes  of vast collection systems that reach well
beyond the city's legal boundaries to bring wastes into one or more
waste treatment plants.  It speaks, perhaps, to the profoundly urban
orientation of Americans that  they have rejected organizations based
on the natural elements of the watershed, but have almost instinc-
tively created sets of local systems based upon core cities.  The
character of such arrangements varies to include informal associations
in which the central city  accepts and treats the waste of its
satellites for a  fee (Portland, Oregon), the county-wide or multi-
county sanitary district composed of a group of contributing
communities (Allegheny County, Pennsylvania), several separately
organized and funded collection systems lying within or cutting across
legal boundaries  to conform to physical configurations of a metropolitan
area  (Los Angeles County,  California), and highly concentrated unit
systems with independent funding  and a high degree of regulatory and
operational autonomy  (Chicago,  Illinois).  The form of the arrangement
may be dictated by local preferences, but  the function of the
city  as the foundation of  metropolitan waste handling is generally
accepted.

      The State-wide system is a  recent development that is founded
upon  several evolving  influences—some provisions of the Clean Water
Restoration Act that provide strong Federal incentives to State plan-
ning  and financial assistance, rivalry between State and local
governments, the  entry of  States  into financial assistance programs for
local waste handling,  the  growing bureaucratic strength of the
                                  145

-------
technicians who administer State pollution control programs, and an
advanced level of pollution abatement capabilities that in most
States has created a need for disciplined and orderly system main-
tenance postures in the conduct of environmental control policies.
As with metropolitan systems, the emerging State-wide systems appear
to be taking on separate configurations that reflect the political
institutions and traditions of States, as well as the regulatory
philosophy of the individuals or groups designing the system.
Maryland, New York, and Ohio have all proposed to enter with great
vigor into the conduct of local waste handling programs, obtaining
their sanction and effectiveness from the use of State funds for
investment purposes and at least modest operating assistance to
communities.  Less formal or less fully formed systems would appear
to be developing in an almost organic fashion in New Jersey, Rhode
Island, and Delaware, where the limited geographic reach of the State
and highly developed pollution control capabilities create a
situation requiring staged, coordinated extensions of pollution
control activities.

                            Effectiveness

      Existence of an organized regional waste handling system provides
no assurance of effective pollution control, but effectiveness of the
systematic processes is their chief theoretical merit.  The core of
the concept is recognition of the fact that not all discharges are
equally polluting:  relative magnitude of discharge, characteristics
of receiving waters, and nature of discharge all play a part in
determining the polluting potential of an effluent.  The regional
strategy for pollution abatement depends upon a simple process of
reasonable allocation.  Resources gathered from all elements of the
system are applied in the fashion that reflects the ordinal signifi-
cance of the elements of a given set of conditions.  The most
pollutional influences are controlled first in point in time, the
more critical situations are more closely controlled.

      Minimum conditions for effectiveness, then, are comprehensive
application of controls to sources of pollution, and discriminating
application of those controls.  Unless the functional powers of the
system managers include the ability to draw resources from all
constituents and to apply them selectively, the potential to effect
desired water quality goals is dissipated.  Effectiveness, in the
final analysis, depends uoon an abrogation of sovereignty by contri-
butors to the system.  They must forego local choice as to whether
and to what degree they will treat their wastes, and they must supply
revenues that may be made available to other elements of the system.

      The effectiveness of regionalism can not be divorced from politi-
cal considerations.  To operate as a system, reqionalisn requires that
technical decisions over-ride local political distinctions.  Either
voluntarily or through statutory coercion, all significant sources of
                                  146

-------
pollutants must adhere to and share the costs of systematic conditions
if the organization is to be of more than ceremonial consequence.

      Both metropolitan system and proposed State systems diverge  from
the effectiveness requirement in that each accepts somewhat more
limited goals.  The intent of the metropolitan system is in most cases
to provide a means to most conveniently dispose of the liquid wastes
of an urban area.  The prime purpose of the State system is to extend
State control over community actions in the sphere of waste handling,
and to insure the responsible use of State funds advanced to remedy
local financial deficiencies.  Pollution control is almost a collateral
goal; and area or regional cooperation is no more than organizational
technique utilized to facilitate accomplishment of another purpose.
The voluntary nature of the typical metropolitan system testifies  to
the fact that the prime concern is satisfying an imposed—from what-
ever direction—requirement for waste treatment.  Given a voluntary
situation, pollution may  continue through failure of a significant
waste source to join the  system, which then does no more than satisfy
the formal regulatory requirement imposed upon participants.
Similarly, the fact that  State systems largely exclude major sources
of industrial waste, except as these are brought into the system
through the  instrumentality of a community, suggests that the prime
purpose is to amplify the extent of State control over local govern-
ment in the  area of waste handling.  These expedients may be extremely
effective in terms of their own limited goals, but  they are by no
means to be  considered  directly effective in  reducing water pollution.

      But if State and  metropolitan arrangements provide no direct
promise of an increase  in capital effectiveness, due to their lack of
comprehensive authority and  inability to  impose abatement priorities
related to streamflow and other natural  conditions, both hold the
promise of incremental  operating effectiveness.  By imposing operat-
ing  standards and  by  supplying  financial  support, the State or the
metropolitan system should invariably result  in an  overall increase
in the effectiveness with which waste treatment plants are operated.
Moreover, such systems  become  large enough to employ specialized
skills and to satisfy internally their need  for trained operators
through normal processes  of  apprenticeship and  promotion,  something
that no small-scale waste treatment organization  can do.

      The potential effectiveness of  regional systems will become  an
increasingly critical matter as  the  pollution control effort matures;
and  there is good  reason  to  predict  that  over the long  run, attainment
of water quality  standards will  not  be  possible in  many  places  in  the
absence of basin-wide or State-wide  regulatory  and  olanning
institutions.

      Authority  for  the conclusion may  be found in  those watersheds
whose water  quality  has been  intensely  studied—the Willamette, the
                                   147

-------
Snake, the San Joaquin, the Colorado, the Arkansas, the Ohio, the
Potomac, Lake Erie, and Lake Michigan.  Without exception, investi-
gators have found that sewage treatment is only a part of a body of
pollution abatement requirements.  Industrial waste treatment is another,
slightly larger, piece.  A host of land management and water management
practices contribute to the presence of pollution; and these must be
adjusted and monitored if pollution abatement is to be accomplished.
Comprehensive reach, technical virtuosity, and flexible resource
allocations will become increasingly necessary as water oollution
control efforts extend in time and intensity.  Where attention begins
and ends at the sewage outfall—as is likely with local responsibility
for pollution abatement and even with the use of metropolitan waste
treatment systems—pollution will probably be only slightly and locally
diminished.

       In terms  of  effectiveness of national  programs over the near
future period,  it  is  apparent that such programs must  be  related to
existing, viable political organizations, not framed in terms of a
conceptual  apparatus  which can be arranged only with considerable
time  and expense if  at all.  A key to a large prooortion  of the
pollution problems rests  in  the larqe urban  area.  Programs directed
to  this  unit  of government might well prove  to be  the  most effective.

                              Efficiency

       Sizeable  efficiencies  have been attributed  to regional  pollution
control  systems; but these have rested on the assumption  of  flexible,
watershed-based applications.  Failure to translate the theoretical
organizational  pattern into  practice  has  largely  short-circuited
attainment  of the  particular efficiencies that are thought to be
peculiar to regional  systems.

       Efficiency considerations, however, must be thought to  underlie
the most vigorous  form of regional pollution control  organization  to
be found in the United States.   Development  of metropolitan  waste
handling procedures has  stemmed  largely  from the economies of scale
that the practice  affords.   Larger plants  involve lower  unit costs.  A
high ratio of transmission facilities to  treatment facilities provides
a longer average life for the body of physical  capital employed.
System size permits greater labor  specialization, more complete
worker utilization, and continuity  of staffing.   A broader  financial
base reduces lumpiness in capital  allocation and tends to ameliorate
 impacts of money market and other  financial  constraints.   All of these
 scale advantages adhere in theory  to any broad-based  regional system;
 but they are most closely associated with metropolitan areas because
of the geographic and administrative coherence  of such a  region.

       Economies of scale are not,  however,  the kind of savings  that
 are distinctive to regional  systems.  The unrealized  economies  of
                                  148

-------
flexibility and oertinence are the ones that proponents of such
systems systems had hoped would develop from application of reqional
principles.

      Such economies had been expected to flow from attention to
underlying physical imperatives and from aoplication of least cost
solutions.  The formulation  techniques are straightforward and
relatively undemanding.  Development of computer technology has
enhanced their breadth  and flexibility enormously, though the
technical concepts were applied on a limited basis well before the
general availability of computer  techniques.

      Unfortunately, all such solutions have two things in common.
They  require  some waste sources to treat to a much higher degree
than  others—and  usually such waste  sources are factories.  And they
include some  in-stream  measures for  which no community  can be assessed
responsibility under existing regulatory procedures.  Unequal imposi-
tion  of controls, with  no  direct  increase in benefits obtained by
those whose  costs are  increased thereby, would  create  such obvious
problems of  administration that  it  is  not at all difficult to see
why optimizinq systems  have  not  been utilized.   In the  absence of
a method for sharing  the  savings  among all  components  of  the  system,
the promised efficiencies  of river  basin pollution control programs
are unlikely to  be  obtained.

                                Equity

       Equity considerations  are,  in  theory,  served more completely by
a  full-fleshed  river basin system of pollution  control  that  includes
proportional  user charges  than  by any other approach that has been
devised.   The broadening  of the financial  base to  include all  inhabi-
tants of a watershed is consistent with the unassignable nature  of
benefits  conferred  and with the inter-related  nature of damages
occasioned.   (In large measure, the same judgement applies to State-
wide  systems, and for the same reasons.)   By assigning costs  on  the
basis of least cost solutions,  the basin system comes as close as  is
humanly possible to establishing an equitable cost of pollution
control.'  By distributing locational and scale advantages as  well  as
by reducing the charges (50-75% of the total, judging by FWPCA model
studies)  atributable to institutional and organizational resistance,
 the basin system is intended to balance actual pollution control
 costs with remedial charges, and so to reduce the inequities occasion-
 ed by uneconomic behavior of those interests seeking to avert or shift
 costs  as well as by the diseconomies incurred by the self-interested
 behavior of pollution  control groups  seeking to increase their
 portion of national income.
                                   149

-------
                            Practicability

     We are presented with the anomalous situation of a means to
organize for pollution control that is apparently superior to any
existing procedure in terms of equity, efficiency, and effectiveness,
and yet one that  is used only on a very limited scale and with
modifications that seem to detract from, rather than add to its
virtues.

     There are no technological constraints.  Limitations on applica-
tion that trace to deficient knowledge of physical conditions in
waterbodies can be remedied.  The method is wholly consistent with
Federal policies, as contained in the Federal Water Pollution Control
Act.

     Yet Americans have shown no inclination to pursue the policies
required to develop river basin pollution control systems.  To the
contrary, the main thrust of State policy, and of Federal policy as
outlined in the guidelines for adoption of interstate water quality
standards, has been to go down the line of uniform waste treatment
requirements, local rather than regional responsibility, State regu-
lation, and adversary enforcement proceedings rather than cooperation
and acceptance of technically induced courses of action.

     The operative element 1n determining public acceptance of river
basin pollution control systems would seem to be the fact that such
systems relate to few, if any, of the existing procedures of
American governments.  They represent a foreign accretion, a perhaps
functional but isolated additional layer in the structure of inter-
governmental relations.  And when it is considered that independent
financial status is one of the prime essentials for effective opera-
tion of such systems, it becomes clear that their implementation
would take pollution control out of reach of normal  local government
decisions, and set it apart from discussion of the hierarchy of
total public needs for resources.

     American State and local government is generally strong, attuned
to public demand, and sanctioned by tradition.  Quite reasonably—
since they have a working, well understood, and reasonably efficient
method of doing things—citizens and established powers tend to
resent the interposition of independant authorities  that reduce
citizen participation in public processes, and that  receive funds
that local preference might wish to consign to schools or hospitals
or roads or police powers.  In the nation's value system, citizen
participation and citizen control would appear to offer satisfactions
well worth the price of some minor technological diseconomies.
                                  150

-------
      Similar political and cultural value mechanisms impede industrial
participation in regional systems.  It has been demonstrated aqain and
again in water quality studies that industrial waste discharges are of
pivotal  importance, so that the effectiveness of any pollution control
scheme must hinge upon industrial oarticipation.  Indeed, the success
of the Ruhrverbaende may be ascribed entirely to industrialists, who
devised and initiated the system  in the nineteenth century and have
adhered to its requirements ever  since.  The behavioral mode was—
and is—quite consistent with the cooperative, cartelized organization
of German industrial activity,  just as German municipal adherence
to the system conforms to a pattern of routine acceptance of centra-
lized, technical administration.

      American industrial behavior, on the other hand, is conducted
with a considerable degree of competitive activity—and its ritual
code of values places  a  premium on  competition that  is even greater
than the degree  of real  competition would suggest.   Rather than
cooperating  to reduce  the  impact  of external  diseconomies, the
American business manager will attempt to evade the  conseauences of
such actions on  his  costs  or  failing  that, to  insure that his
competitors  will  bear  at least an equal  cost.  Regulation, negotiation,
the  competitive  interposition of  public  interest and private  interest
that marks  the American  system of countervailing cowers—these  prevail
in the  conduct of water  pollution control activities.  They are  not
conducive  to establishment of rationalized regional  systems;  but it
would  be  rash  to contend that the total  and  long  run productivity
that  results from the  opposition  of countervailing  powers is  not well
worth  the  intermediate diseconomies that the system generates.

       Perhaps  it is  an indication of the innate  flexibility generated
by our political and industrial  practices that the  regional systems
concept has been adapted—or is  in the process of  adaptation—to
fit  American conditions.  The central function of  the city  and  the
established pattern of local  public utility  services have accepted the
general  outline  of regionalism in developing the metrooolitan sanitary
district.   State control and the interpenetration  of State  and  local
government activities  are apparent in the development of State-wide
systems,  as in Maryland or New York, where cost-sharing, planning,
and  efficiency standards are evolving from processes that a decade
ago  were directed exclusively to the obvious and^lirrited ends of
control  of contagion and adoption of "good nractice".

       It would seem that regionalism and systems engineering  based on
watershed conditions are not practicable in the United States at this
 time   The institutional mechanisms to implement them generally do not
exist  and may even be  inimical  to some very strong social  Deferences.
Qn the other hand, existing institutions are evolving to Incorporate
many of the desirable features of watershed systems.  The major
 forms of regionalisn that are emerging are, at this time, oerhans
 less efficient than the river basin system.   But they are not only
                                   151

-------
more comfortable in terms of compatability with existing institutions,
they exhibit a rich variety that tends to conform to local conditions.
Over the long pull, the flexibility of interrelated State-wide and
metropolitan systems may prove to have an effectiveness of a high order.

                         Economies of Scale

      One of the principal inducements to regional waste-handling
systems—particularly when viewed in the context of the metropolitan
system rather than the broader terms of the river basin or State-wide
system—is  their presumed ability to activate substantial economies
of scale.

      Analysis of  recorded investments since 1962 raises the possibility
that the particular advantage is not a constant virtue.  There appear
to be significant  discontinuities in application of economies of
scale, at least as these relate to investment.  The dimensions and
findings of that analysis are presented here, but it must be emphasiz-
ed that it  would be premature to base policy decisions upon those
findings.   They are incomplete, in that they deal only with initial
construction costs and are not time-phased.  Interpretation of the
interplay of investment and operating costs, the long  run implications
of the difference  in effective life of treatment and transmission
components  of a system, and consideration of the effects of interest
rates may indicate that the inferred discontinuities of scale
economies in initial investment may be reduced, eliminated, or rein-
forced by more comprehensive consideration of cost factors.

      In theory* the unit costs of waste handling should decline as
size of the system increases.  A generally accepted economic concept
holds that  each incremental unit of product spreads fixed costs over
a larger base, so  that unit costs invariably decline with size; and--
also in theory—there  is no point at which increasing  size should
result in an upward shift in unit costs:  at the point at which
returns to  size become negative, the rational manager will begin to
replicate a system rather than expand it.  (The logic  of the latter
argument is somewhat debatable.  If there is some physical or other
limit to effective optimum size that dictates replication rather
than expansion, the second and succeeding units may be viewed as
subsystems  of a multi-unit system; in which case, unit costs might
properly be calculated on the basis of costs and output of the
aggregated  components.)

      The theory rests on physical as well as financial and organization-
al aspects  of cost.  The general terms of the physical relationship
are expressed by the engineering rule of thumb called  the six-
tenths-power rule, a convention that holds that in the design of a
system the  cost of an incremental unit of capacity is  equal to
                                  152

-------
approximately sixty percent of the cost of an anterior unit of the
same dimensions.  (More precisely:  if X capacity costs Y dollars,
then 3X will cost SY^-6): 30th the economist's and the engineer's  ex-
pression of the concept of economies to scale imply a continuous
assertion of those economies. The economist will usually have at the
back of his mind a general view of marginally diminishing returns  to
size, while the six-tenths-nower rule suggests a constant rate of
continuous accretion of such returns; but the principle is a fixed
feature of either practitioner's view of the world.

 Investigation of the cost of incremental waste handling services
provided through investments made between 1962 and 1968 suggests
very strongly, however, that there is a significant discontinuity in
the expression of waste handling economies to scale.  Figure 8,
presents the results of the analysis, v;hich related unit investment
to size of place.

 The procedure followed in developing the relationship was an
exercise in aggregation.  Total expenditures that were made for
sewers by communities of  a given  size class were divided by additional
population reported to be connected  to  sewers in communities of the
same size class (line A).  Total  expenditures for waste handling
investments in all categories other  than sewers were divided by a
factor equal to 8Q% of all persons added to secondary waste treatment
systems plus 3Q% of all  persons added to primary waste treatment
systems in each size class during the period  (line B).   (The factor
is  intended to provide a  measurement of incremental waste reduction
based on a  rough measure  of waste strength—one person equal to one
population  equivalent of  biochemical oxygen demand—and  a broad
estimate of the average  efficiency of the basic waste  treatment
processes.)  Finally, the mean  contribution to municipal waste  dis-
charges  imposed by  industrial effluents in towns of each  size class
was  taken  into  account by multiplying  increased population served by
a  loading  factor  proper  to  the  size  of  the community  and  then by  the
appropriate treatment  factors and dividing investments other than
those  for  sewers  in  each size class  by  the products  (line C).   (The
multipliers, which  even  and  extend  the  observed  pattern  of the
relationship  of waste  concentrations to persons  served in places  of
a  niven  size were:   0.85 for towns  equal  to  or  less  than  1000,  0.95 for
towns  of  1000  to  2500,  1.15  for towns  of 5000 to  10,000,  1.40 for
towns  of  10,000 to  25,000,  1.67 for towns of 25,000  to 50,000,  1.9 for
towns  of 50,000 to  100,000,  and 2.05 for towns  of 100,000-250,000.
These  were determined  by an  analysis of operating  records for treatment
plants  built  with  the  aid of Federal grants,   c.f.  R.  Michel et al
"Plant Operation  and Maintenance,"   Journal  of the Water Pollution
Control  Federation,   March  1969.)

  Subject to the reliability  of  the  data and  the uncertainties of
cost and population distributions within population  size classes-
the lines  connect  the  juncture  of population class midpoints with
                                  153

-------
                                                         Figure 8

                              UNIT INVESTMENT BY SIZE OF PLACE, FOR  INCREMENTAL
                                         WASTE-HANDLING  CAPABILITIES
                                                         1962-68
500


450


400

350


  III


250


200


150


100


 50


  D
      C-Investment in Treatment Plants & Ancillary
     /   Works Per Unit Waste Reduction. Adjusted
         for Typical Industrial Loading  Pattern
A-Investment in Sewers  Per
   Person Added
                                                 B-lnveslment in Treatment
                                                    Plants 8 Ancillary Works
                                                    Per Unit of Incremental
                                                    Domestic Waste Reduction
                                       1000
                                             10DOO

                                     Units  Processed
100,000
WUIOll

-------
unit investments—the Figure may be thought to provide a fairly good
estimate of what it has cost to connect one more person to a  sewer
system (line A), to treat the wastes of one more person to the average
level provided by a community of the size in which he lives (line B),
and the cost to provide that same average degree of treatment to an
additional population equivalent of wastes from either domestic or
industrial sources  (line C).  There may be significant divergences
between actual unit costs and the indicated costs at any point along
the curves, but their general shape must be considered to be  accurate
if the data is accurate.

     The graphed lines  indicate clearly, if somewhat imprecisely,
that unit  investment requirements drop off initially as size  of place
increases; but as population reaches about 10,000, a rather sharp
increase in unit waste  handling costs may be anticipated.

     Although the pattern of discontinuous application of economies
of scale may  seem to conflict with theory, there is no reason to
doubt that the phenomenon exists.  With respect to waste treatment,
there are  well defined  explanations for the increase in unit costs
for  larger towns and for cities.   (These are discussed below.)  For
sewers, however, we can only conjecture about  the influences that
press costs upward  for  towns of a given size.

      Possible explanations  for rising  incremental sewer costs  in
larger  places include  higher excavation costs  and other disruption
charges  in built up areas,  greater  likelihood  of the interposition of
terrain problems as area expands with  population, more complex  systems
in larger  areas, lower population  density  in outlying  areas  that may
be served  by  larger towns,  and need  to include within  the  system
substantial areas that  are  locations  for commercial or  industrial
development and  so  provide  limited  additions to the body of  users
relative  to the  area  of additional  service.  Should such factors,
indeed,  be responsible  for  the  increase in  unit sewer  investments  for
towns of  ten  to  twenty-five thousand,  it  is not unreasonable to
infer a second  discontinuity  in  expression  of  economies  of scale  that
may  occur in  very  large cities,  where the  same complexities  of size
exist in  an enlarged  fashion   as  compared  to cities  in the upper  size
classes considered  in  the  analysis.   (While the additional discontin-
uities  may be inferred, it  has  proved impossible  to  document them.
Reporting  procedures  are  such  that it is  not  possible  to distinguish
between investments made  by cities and those made  by  large consolidated
sanitary districts—the basic  reason  that  unit investment  calculations
were not made for  places  of more than 250,000  population.)

      Reasons  for the  apparent  intermediate diseconomies of scale  are
far  easier to assign  with  some  authority in the case  of waste treat-
ment.   One very significant factor—the relative  rise of industrial
wasteloads with increasing size  of place—has  been considered in  the
analysis by  assigning multipliers to account  for the indicated


                                   155

-------
prevalence of industrial wastes at each population size class.  The
effect of the adjustment is to sharply reduce dimensions of indicated
diseconomies.  It is obvious that to assign costs entirely on a
per-capita basis is to exaggerate unit costs when a significant
portion of capacity is utilized for industrial wastes.  Because the
proportion of industrial wastes handled by a system typically
increases with population, the exaggeration becomes increasingly
operative as population increases.

     Also significant to the pattern of unit costs is distribution of
treatment processes by size of place.  As hydraulic loading increases,
a shift in the factors of production occurs from land-intensive treat-
ment processes to capital-intensive methods.  Because construction
costs alone enter into the calculation, the interaction of land and
construction costs is not reflected in the curves of Figure £ .
(Land costs are highly variable, but tend to rise with population
concentration; so it is unlikely that consideration of land costs would
make any significant change in the shape of the cost to size curves.
If land prices did not characteristically increase at multiples
greater than demand for land for waste treatment needs, then the shift
to facilities-intensive treatment methods would be unlikely to occur.)

     The manner in which increased demand for Vv'aste treatment capacity
influences preferences among treatment methods is indicated very
clearly in Table 53, which lists the relative prevalence of treat-
ment processes in 1968 by size of plant.  In some cases, the "normal"
construction cost for a 1 million gallon per day plant as presented
in -lodern Sewage Treatment Plants, How Much Do They Cost?  is indicated
in the table.  In other cases, statistical analyses of the correlation
of plant size and construction costs are not available.  The general
ranking of costs, however, is known to follow the pattern presented in
Figure 9.

      Figure 9 is not calibrated for relative unit costs and removals
except in the most elementary sense.  The position of a process
simnly indicates that under noroal conditions it costs more per unit
of capacity than processes that aopear below it in the figure and less
than processes that appear above it.  Degree of waste removal, too, is
presented only in a "more than" or "less than" sense.  It should be
understood, too, that the indicated relationships are by no means
invariable.  The less costly "post-secondary" processes may sometimes
conveniently be substituted for secondary treatment by small  towns,
in which case they might be little, if any, more costly than  biological
filters.  The basic principle that capital replaces land as size of
place increases definitely limits the application of septic tanks,
lagoons, and land disposal, to relatively snail  communities.

     The relationships embodied in Figure 9 help to explain the
discontinuities that have been found to exist in application  of
economies to scale in waste treatment.   Table 53 indicates that the
                                 156

-------
                                                 TABLE  53
                                     Distribution of  Waste  Treatment
                                        Processes by  Size of  Plant
 Type of Treatment
                           Percent of  Plants  of  Size  Class  by  Type  of Treatment
                                   Design  Flow,  Million  Gallons  Per Day
                              .25-  .50-   1.0-
Imhoff & Septic Tanks  13.3   7.2   4.8
     Primary Treatment
     Chemical Treatment
01   Biological Filters
     Activated Sludge
     Lagoons
     Extended Aeration
     Other Secondary
     Land Disposal
     Intmt.  Sand  Filters
     Tertiary Treatment
     Number  of Plants
     Percent of Total
(a) = Less than 0.1
NA = Not available
V 1957-59 Dollars
                        0.1    0.3   0.6
                       22.0  41.5  43.1
                        6.2  11.9  13.3    17.5
                       39.5  20.4  15.4
                        8.8   5.6   4.5
                        1.2   1.5   2.1
                        1.4   0.4   0.6
                        3.0   1.0   0.7
                        (a)    (a)   (a)

                       6973  1677  1279    1832
                       56.3  13.6  10.3    14.8
                                                                                                                    Expectable
.0-
.999
2,1
10.3
1.7
'5.7
7.5
8.0
1.8
1.6
0.4
0.4
0.4
832
4.8
5.0-
9.999
0.7
28.6
1.7
35.0
25.5
4.1
1.7
1.7
1.0


294
2.4
10.0-
29.999

34.7
4.2
23.5
31.5
1.4
0.9
2.3
0.5
0.5
0.5
213
1.7
30.0-
49.999
4.3
30.4
2.2
17.4
32.6
2.2
2.2
6.5


2.2
46
0.4
50.0-
99.999

34.5
13.8
6.9
41.4

3.4




29
0.2
100.0-
199.999 200.000
4.0
28.0 33.3

12.0
36.0 50.0

4.0
16.0 16.6



25 6
0.2 0.1
Percent of
All Plants
9.3
9.9
0.6
30.6
10.6
27.9
6.6
1.5
1.0
2.0
0.1
12374
100.0
Cost Per M(
Capacity !_/
$237,000
235,000
235,000
288,000
321,000
68,000
NA
NA
NA
MA
NA



-------
                            Fiqure  9

                     GENERALIZED RANKING OF
                     UNIT COST AND REMOVAL
                  EFFICIENCIES OF CONVENTIONAL
                 WASTE TREATMENT  PROCESSES
                             REMOVAL
PRIMARY TREATMENT
   PROCESSES
SECONDARY TREATMENT PROCESSES
    TERTIARY
TREATMENT PROCESSES
                                158
                                                         0

-------
likelihood that a high construction cost treatment method v.'ill be
applied increases directly with size of olant.

     Time, as well as land availability and required treatment effec-
tiveness, plays a part in the nix of treatment methods.  Iiuhoff tanks
and community septic tanks represent hangovers of an obsolescent
technology; it is seldom that a community would install either of then
today.  Similarly, it is extremely unlikely that any small community
west* of the Mississippi or south of the i'ason-Dixon line would install
a primary treatment plant of any description.  The much higher removal
efficiencies and much lower costs available with the use of lagoons
have made them standard technology for small  communities in most of
the nation during the last ten years.  Indeed, the point at which the
investment cost  to size function for treatment plants  and ancillary
works  turns upward in Fiqure 8 corresponds very closely with what
has generally served  ?s the effective limit of application of lagoons--
that  is,  a town  of about ten thousand persons, or an hydraulic capacity
of a nil lion gallons  per day.
                                   159

-------
                              APPENDIX

                   THE FACILITIES EVALUATION MODEL
     The mathematical modeling technique employed as part of the
cost analysis for municipal waste treatment plants was devised
to calculate the following, based on the 1962 and 1968 Municipal
Waste Inventory data supplied by the States and municipalities:

     1.  current replacement value of facilities in place

     2.  value of recognized improvements needed in treatment or
         operation of waste treatment systems as stated in the
         1962 and 1968 Municipal Waste Inventory

     The scope of answers  attainable using this technique has
answered questions as to how much money would have to be spent
to replace treatment plants that are still in existence; what the
current inventory (backlog) of needs is, and what it was in 1962.
The technique can also evaluate the additional treatment costs
needed in future timeframes, based on current facilities.

     The current replacement value of facilities in place was cal-
culated on the basis of costs experienced in building facilities
with similar design  flow and removal efficiencies.  This analysis
included a measure of variability in the cost per unit  treated.
The costs associated with  the stated needs in the 1962  and 1968
inventories included both  variability in projected design flow
and in cost per unit treated.   This modeling approach,  in addition
to incorporating variability as indicated, provides a mechanism
to handle a  large amount of data with the ability to vary conditions
parametrically to determine the effect  of the change of one variable
on the stability of  the outcome.

     The  results of  these  analyses are  presented in the body of
this report.

     A diagram of  the  calculation  scheme  follows.
                                161

-------
                                                FACILITIES EVALUATION MODELS
                                                       GENERALIZED LOGIC
en
ro
                       6399 KEEPS
                      1 NEW PLANT
                      2 REPLACE PLANT
                      3 UPGRADE PLANT
                      4 ENLARGE PLANT
                      5 DISINFECTION
                      6 CONNECTION
                      7 OTHER
                                       CURRENT
                                      REPLACEMENT
                                        VALUE
                                      (12.4 BILLION)
   / COST I! \
—-{    SIZE   V
   V  FACTOR J

-------
MAI

k |
N i
!
1
AVG & SD of FLOW '
._ .„.._... i
, t i
each pass or r«. J
* I
'- - ~ 1 |
time regional COST [ «
costs are
calculated
di i cuninun i Lies i
in region i
i i
1 SAVE COST in _] i
| TOTAL AREA 	 i
M« M . *
1
1
i
i
i
• i
i
each region
i
FIND AVG & SD of '
TOTAL COSTS 	 '


END
                                                The solid blocks
                                                indicate the basic
                                                work units to be
                                                explained after the
                                                diagram.  The dashed
                                                lines indicate the
                                                program flow with the
                                                number of times each
                                                box is entered listed
                                                with the dashed lines.
1.  MAIN:

      Main reads and selects the data to be manipulated and totalled
in succeeding portions of the program.

2.  AVG & SD of FLOW:

      This routine calculated the average and standard deviation of
actual per capita flows observed at the existing waste treatment
facilities by size of place (1-10).  These values are used later in
the program in the cost calculations.  Let us refer to these flows
as AQ and SDQ for average and standard deviation of flow.

3.  COST:

      This portion of the program calculates treatment plant costs
(on an individual basis but aggregated by type of need and region
studied).  These costs were calculated basically as follows for each
plant:

      a.  Calculate a population served for 25 years from the present
based on growth factors by size of place (1-10).  This yields a 25
year design population.  Parametrically varying the growth rate by
size of place by +2B% of the expected growth changed the cost answers
less than
10%.
                                163

-------
     b.  Calculate the total flow from the plant based on (a) and
the average and standard deviation of the flow per capita as cal-
culated in AV & SD of flow by using a normal (0,1) random deviate
(RN) as follows:

     Total Flow = population projection x (AQ + RN x SDQ).
     Bounds were set on the flow value.  The calculated flow value
was then used to determine a cost as follows:

     Using a cost curve which represents the average unit cost per
total flow in a plant calculate the cost...but recognize that the
average cost curve also has variability.  So using the average and
standard deviation of costs for that particular flow calculate costs
in much the same manner as the total flow by using a normal (0,1)
random deviate.  Pictorially the process looks like this...
       $
                                avq per capita
                                     flow
                                multiplied by
                                  population
where the shaded
area would repre-
sent the possible
value of cost if
both flow and costs
were restricted to
say one standard
deviation (a) about
the mean.
                                avg unit cost
                                    curve
                 FLOW
     At this point, it is appropriate to  interject one paragraph
relative to the calculation of in-place facilities value.  The dia-
gram above can best be used for this purpose.  Assume that the
abscissa FLOW represents design flow at present facilities as listed
in the Municipal Waste Inventories.  We can  then use the average
plant flow line on the diagram with no deviation for a representation
of design flow which is given.  We still  must, recognize the variability
of costs.  Therefore, instead of having an area over which the costs
can vary, we recognize only a variability along the design flow line.
                                164

-------
     We return now to the discussion of backlog costs.  A cost is
calculated for each community expressing a need.  The cost functions
relate to the specified needs and where necessary include a factor
for ancillary works.  The costs for each community in a region are
summed, and when all the communities in the region have been analyzed
a total cost for the region is obtained.  Each region was simulated
either 10 or 25 times on a community by community basis and the 10
or 25 total cost values were analyzed to determine the mean and
standard deviation of total costs likely from the region.  Increasing
the number of iterations for simulation of total regional costs from
10 times to 25 times produced almost no cost change (about 3 to 4%).
On this basis, 10 analyses per region were used for most calculations.
The mean cost was used as the indicator of the regional cost.  The
standard deviation is an indicator of the stability of the mean and
generally followed the trend in the variance of the flow values in
the regions.

     There are seven basic needs categories reflecting the needs
recognized by States and municipalities and included  in the 1962
and 1968 Municipal Waste Inventories.   Costs were calculated for
each need, based on costs determined by analysis of unit costs for
projects receiving  Federal grant assistance and estimates of maximum
reasonable costs where other information was not available.  The num-
bers obtained can be challenged, but the orders of magnitude of these
values are believed to scope the problem.  It  is noted that this
approach is not applicable to  reliable  costing  for the design of any
particular plant, but  rather provides  valuable  aggregate values.
The seven needs categories follow, with an explanation of the method
of analysis and the basic  rationale:

New  Plant

      New plant  indicates the need  for  construction of a  facility
where none  presently exists.

      Where the  plant analyzed  was  noncoastal,  secondary  treatment
was  used  as  the need  in  the  form of an activated  sludge  plant with
 a multiplicative  factor  for  ancillary  works  included in  the costs.
 The  basic equations for  cost are:

      a.   Log(cost)  =  5.6062  -  0.3537 x log(flow)

      b.   log (random component of cost) = RN x 0.175

 Total cost = 10(a+b)  x Flow  x factor for ancillary works + 1.0)
                                165

-------
     Where the discharge was to a coastal outfall,primary treatment
was assumed to be adequate under current water quality standards.
The multiplication factor was used again in this calculation for
ancillary works.

     The basic equations follow:

     a.  log  (cost)  =  5.3704 -  0.44604 x loq  (flow)

     b.  log  (random component  of cost) = RN  x 0.188

 The total  cost equation is  the  same  as above.

 Enlarge Existing Facilities

      These costs were  based on  primary  treatment plant costs  for
 coastal discharges with the ancillary factor set to  zero;  and
 secondary treatment plant costs with zero  ancillary  factor for  non-
 coastal discharges.  The rationale  here was that it  would  cost  more
 to enlarge facilities  than to just  add  on  the component of the  plant,
 because existing facilities would have  to  be worked  around during
 construction and provisions would have  to  be made to keep  the plant
 in operation for as much of the time as possible.

 Upgrading

      These costs for upgrading facilities  based on construction grants
 costs for similar activities was formulated as follows:

      a.  log (cost) =  5.450 - 0.4073 x log(flow)

      b.  log (random component of cost) = RN x 0.231

 Total cost = lo(a+b) x Flow

 Replacement of Existing Plant

      These costs are the same as for a new plant, except that no
 factor has been added  for ancillary works.   In the instances where
 the plant discharges to a coastal zone the treatment  is primary;
 where  discharge is  to  a non-coastal zone, treatment is secondary.
                                  166

-------
ChTorination Costs

     Chiorination costs were calculated from:   A Compilation of
Cost Information for Conventional  and Advanced Wastewater Treatment
Plants and Processes. FWPCA, Cincinnati, 1967.

     a.  log (cost) = 3.958 + 0.469 x log(flow)

     b.  log (random component of cost) = RN x 0.030

Total cost = io(a+b) x Flow

Improved Operation or Better Use of Existing Facilities

     The cost here was considered basically administrative in nature,
with some  possibility of minor modification of treatment methods.
Chlorination, a minor capital modification, was used as a surrogate
for all investment  in this  category.  Therefore, the chlorination
costs were used as  explained previously.


Connection to Adequate  Existing Sewer System

      This  cost was  considered  to  be  no greater than building a
new  facility with the  associated  ancillary works.  Therefore,  these
costs  were used.   The  rationale was  that if the cost were less,
a rationally administered community  would choose to build its  own
 plant.


 Scheduling Procedures

      Values derived from the procedures described above are the
 basic inputs to the investment scheduling model, which takes the
 derived current replacement value of facilities together with the
 derived value of needed facilities (the "backlog"), and calculates
 their condition under any  chosen assumption about amount of invest-
 ment.

      The  scheduling procedure utilized  to develop this report
 depended  largely on trial  and error  applications of investment
 amounts over a series of time frames.   (Subseguently, a more
 sophisticated procedure was developed  in which the program was
                                167

-------
calibrated to Increase or decrease amount of investment, according
to the degree to which a schedule attained established success
boundaries—defined in terms of backlog reduction.  Such a search-
ing program proved to be necessary to deal with the time-consuming
calculating problems involved in dealing with a range of require-
ments for fifty-four individual investment units.)

     The calculations performed are, in order:

     1.  Before each set of passes, increase the value of both
         plant  in place and backlog to 1.035 of its previous
         value—to account  for the assumed level of inflation.

     2.  Establish  .029 of  the value of capital In place as the
         amount of the annual recapitalization requirement.

     3.  Establish  .033 of  the value of capital in place as the
         amount of the annual growth requirement.

     4.  Reduce the amount  of the assumed  investment  by the
         amount of the recapitalization requirement.

     5.  Reduce the amount  of the assumed  investment  by the amount
         of  the annual growth requirement:   if the amount of  the
         investment remaining after sten  (4)  is equal  to or
         greater  than the amount of the annual growth requirement,
         the  value is transferred entirely to the value of capital
         in  place;  if the amount of investment remaining after
         step (4) is less than the amount  of  the  annual growth
         requirement, the value of investment remaining after
         step (4) is transferred to capital  in place,  and the
         difference between that amount and  the total  growth
         requirement is transferred to the backlog.

     6.  If a positive value remains after the investment amount
         has  been reduced by step (4) and  steo (5) that amount
         is transferred as  a negative value  to the backlog and
         as a positive value to the amount of capital  in nlace.

     The procedure is then  repeated, using the newly  established
values of capital in place  and backlog, until the backlog is  either
eliminated or begins to increase.
                              168

                                        •s U. S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE : 19TO O - 384-036

-------