IDENTIFICATION
OF DANGEROUS LEVELS
   OF LEAD IN PAINT,
    DUST, AND SOIL
     TLE IV OF TSCA
     SECTION 403
AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS

 DRAFT: January 10, 1994

-------
                                             Associates Inc.
                                             IDENTIFICATION
                                         OF DANGEROUS LEVELS
                                            OF LEAD IN PAINT,
                                             DUST, AND SOIL

                                             TITLE IV OF TSCA
                                                SECTION 403

                                        AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS

                                          DRAFT: January 10,  1994
        Prepared by:
        Abt Associates Inc.
        4800 Montgomery Lane
        Bethesda, MD 20814
        Contract Number 68-D2-0175
        Work Assignment 2-08
                                                 Preparedfor:
                                                Nishkam Agarwal
                                             Regulatory Impacts Branch
                                     Economics, Exposure and Technology Division
                                       Office of Pollution Prevention and Toxics
                                        U.S. Environmental Protection Agency
Authors:
Greg Michaels
Frank Letkiewicz
Alice Tome
Brad Firlie
Amy Benson
Leland Deck
Hampdcn Square • Suite 600 • 4800 Montgomery Lane  • Bethesda. Maryland • 20814-5341 • (301)913-0500 • Fax. (301) 652-3618/3839

-------
                              ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

       We would like to acknowledge the contributions of Dr. Nishkam Agarwal who directed
this project for the Regulatory Impacts Branch, Office of Pollution Prevention and Toxics,
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. His guidance set the agenda for the entire analysis
and sharpened the focus of its results.  We also appreciate the contributions of Dr. Gary
Cole, also of the Regulatory Impacts Branch, to the early development of the model which
was employed in this study.

       Finally, we would like to recognize the efforts  ofToddAagaard, Karl Kuellmer,
Michael Mailer, and Cassandra De Young ofAbt Associates. Their work to distill large
amounts of data and other information was critical to the conduct of our analyses and to the
presentation of our results in this report.

-------
                        TABLE OF CONTENTS
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY	      i
     ES.l BACKGROUND	' ' .' '   i
     ES.2 AGENCY APPROACH TO SECTION 403 REQUIREMENTS  .....   i
     ES.3 PURPOSE OF THE ANALYSIS	  u
     ES.4 SYNOPSIS OF THE BENEFIT-COST APPROACH	  ii
          ES.4.1      General Overview  	  ii
          ES.4.2      Abatement Decision Rules	iii
          ES.4.3      Costs	'.'.'.  iv
          ES.4.4      Benefits	viii
     ES.S BENEFIT-COST  ANALYSIS  OF  ALTERNATIVE  HAZARD
          LEVELS 	xii
          ES.5.1      Results for the Five Abatement Decision Rules	xii
     ES.7 SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS  	xvi
     ES.8 IMPACTS OF THE PROPOSED RULE	              xviii
     ES.9 CONCLUSION	'. . xx

1.  INTRODUCTION	       1_!
     1.1   PROVISIONS OF RULE	 1-1
     1.2   STATUTORY AUTHORITY	1-1
     1.3   PURPOSE AND CONTENTS OF REPORT 	1-4

2.  REGULATORY BACKGROUND	  2-1
     2.1   INTRODUCTION	'm'm\'m \2-\
          2.1.1       Lead as a Public Health Problem	2-1
     2.2   REGULATION OF LEAD PRODUCTS, ENVIRONMENTAL AND
          WORKPLACE RELEASES OF LEAD, AND LEAD IN DRINKING
          WATER  	2-2
          2.2.1       Lead in Paint	 .2-2
          2.2.2       Lead in Gasoline	2-2
          2.2.3       Other Lead-based Products  	2-2
          2.2.4       Environmental and Workplace Releases of Lead	2-3
          2.2.5       Lead in Drinking Water  	2-3
          2.2.6       Resulting Reduction in Blood Lead Levels  	2-4

-------
      2.3   EFFORTS TO REDUCE LEAD-BASED PAINT, DUST AND SOIL
            IN RESIDENTIAL AREAS	2-4
            2.3.1       Current Estimates of Exposure	2-4
            2.3.2       Federal Regulatory Activities to Decrease Exposure to
                       Lead-Based Paint in Erieting Housing	2-5
            2.3.3       Federal Guidelines and Other Activities Related to Lead
                       in Soils and Dust	2-8
            23.4       State and Local Programs to Reduce Exposure to Lead-
                       based Paint, Dust and Soil	2-9
            2.3.5       Benefits of Defining a Lead Standard for Paint, Dust,
                       and Soil  	2-13
      2.4   REFERENCES	2-14

3. PROBLEM DEFINITION AND REGULATORY OPTIONS	   3-1
      3.1   RISK SUMMARY	3-1
            3.1.1       Characterization of Exposure	3-3
            3.1.2       Determining Blood Lead Distributions 	3-11
            3.1.3       Estimated Incidence of Adverse Health Effects	3-17
            3.1.4       Extrapolation of Fust Model Year  Results to  Full
                       Modelling Time Frame	3-22
            3.1.5       Discussion of Results for Baseline Risk Assessment   . . . 3-35
      3.2   MARKET FAILURE  	3-40
      3.3   NEED FOR FEDERAL REGULATION	 3-43
      3.4   REGULATORY OPTIONS	 3.44
            3.4.1       Information Provision	3.44
            3.4.2       Other Regulatory Options  	3-46
                            ****•••••*••••••••••••••••••••••» J™^fO

4. COSTS	4_!
      4.1   METHOD FOR COST ANALYSIS	                     4-1
      4.2   DATA	'. '.4_!
            4.2.1       Testing and Abatement Costs of Lead in Dust 	4-2
            4.2.2       Testing and Abatement Costs for Lead-based Paint  .... 4-3
            4.2.3       Testing and Abatement Costs of Lead in Soil	4-11
            4.2.4       Combined Abatement Scenario Costs	4-15
            4.2.5       Enforcement Costs	4-16
      4.3 SAMPLE COST CALCULATION	          4-20
      4.4   RESULTS 	. . 4-23
            4.4.1       Total Abatement Costs  	4-23
            4.4.2       Quantity  of  Hazardous   Waste  Generated  by
                       Abatement	4-27
      4.5    REFERENCES .  . .
                             •••••••••••••••••••••••

-------
5. BENEFITS	       5_1
      5.1   GENERAL ASSUMPTIONS	 . . . . .5-1
           5.1.1      Decision Rule Assumptions	5-2
           5.1.2      Abatement Choice Assumptions	5-5
           5.1.3      Post-Abatement Exposure Condition Assumptions	5-5
      5.2   BENEFITS MODELING PROCESS  	5-8

           EFFECTS  	5.9
      5.4   VALUATION OF BENEFITS	 5-17
           5.4.1      Valuing Lost IQ Points	5-17
           5.4.2      Valuing Increased Educational Resources  	5-20
           5.4.3      Valuing Neonatal Mortality 	5-21
      5.5   COMPUTING BENEFITS FOR FULL MODEL PERIOD  	. . 5-21
      5.6   RESULTS OF MONETIZED BENEFITS 	5-23

6. BENEFIT-COST ANALYSIS	  6-1
      6.1   BASIS FOR EVALUATION	 .6-1
      6.2   ALTERNATIVE DECISION RULES	;	6-1
           6.2.1      Voluntary Optimum Decision Rule	6-2
           6.2.2      Decision Rules Based Upon Induced Abatements	6-8
           6.2.3      Other Decision Rules to  Consider  	    6-25
      6.3   SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION	6-31

7. SENSITIVITY ANALYSES	7-1
      7.1   POTENTIAL SENSITIVITY ANALYSES	 .7-1
      7.2   ALTERNATIVE COST ASSUMPTIONS 	7-3
      7.3   ALTERNATIVE DISCOUNTING PROCEDURE	 7-10
      7.4   SUPPLEMENTAL BENEFITS  FOR ADULTS  AND  EXISTING
           CHILDREN	7_24
      7.5   REFERENCES	 7-29
      7.A   APPENDIX	 7-30

8. IMPACTS OF THE PROPOSED RULE	8-1
      8.1   REGULATORY FLEXIBILITY ANALYSIS  .... . . .  . . .' . . . . . .' . 8-1
           8.1.1      Reason and Legal Basis for Agency Action  	8-1
           8.1.2      Definition of Small Entity and Affected Populations .... 8-2
           8.1.3      Data Availability	8-5
           8.1.4      Regulatory Options	8-5
     8.2   PAPERWORK REDUCTION ACT ANALYSIS	 . 8-5
     8.3   TRADE IMPACTS ANALYSIS	8-6
     8.4   ANALYSIS OF IMPACTS ON TECHNOLOGICAL INNOVATION  . . 8-6

-------
8.5   EQUITY IMPACTS ANALYSIS	8-6
      8.5.1        Age of Housing Stock	8-7
      8.5.2        Regional Distribution	8-8
      8.53        Cost of Housing	8-9
      8.5.4        Income 	8-10
      8.5.5        Affordability	8-11
      8.5.6        Race	8-22
      8.5.7        Other Sociofeconomic Variables	8-22
      8.5.8        Data Limitations  	8-24
      8.5.9        Environmental Equity Conclusions	8-24
8.6   REFERENCES	8-25

-------
                              EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
 ES.l  BACKGROUND

       On October 28, 1992, Congress enacted the Housing and Community Development Act
 of 1992. Title X of that Act - the Residential Lead-Based Faint Hazaid Reduction Act of 1992
 ~ included among other things an amendment adding "Title IV - Lead Exposure Reduction" to
 the Toxic Substances Control Act (TSCA). Among the various requirements of TSCA Title IV
 are those set forth under Section 403 - Identification of Dangerous Levels of Lead.  Section 403
 reads as follows:

       "Within  18 months after  the  enactment of this tide,  the Administrator  shall
       promulgate regulations which  shall identify, for purposes of this  title and the
       Residential Lead-Based Paint Hazard Reduction Act of 1992, lead-based paint
       hazards, lead-contaminated dust, and lead-contaminated soil."
ES.2  AGENCY APPROACH TO SECTION 403 REQUIREMENTS

       The Agency's approach to the TSCA Section 403 requirements is to establish quantitative
standards for lead in residential soil and dust, and a qualitative standard for lead in paint.  That
is, for soil and dust, EPA will identify specific, measurable levels of lead in these media as the
hazard levels.   For lead paint, the Agency has determined that the condition  and location
(accessibility) of the surfaces bearing the lead paint are more indicative of the potential for a
hazard to be present than are measurements of the amount of lead present on those painted
surfaces. Consequently, the lead paint hazard will emphasize those characteristics rather than
a quantifiable level of lead on painted surfaces.

       The Agency recognizes that, from a public health perspective, human exposure to lead
at any level is undesirable.  However, the Agency also recognizes that the costs to society and
individuals to reduce lead exposure from paint, soil and dust can be substantial. Therefore, from
an overall public welfare perspective,, it is important to  balance properly the public health
benefits achieved from reducing exposure to lead with the costs that are incurred by society to
achieve those benefits.

       The Agency also recognizes that while the incidence and severity of adverse effects of
lead generally  operate along a continuum of exposure levels, there are different degrees  of
potential human health hazards that suggest different forms of remedies to reduce or prevent
exposure. The analysis  in the current report illustrates the significant contribution to  social
welfare that could be made by fitting a remedial response to the particular hazards of a home.
 The Agency will also suggest the types of responses believed to be appropriate for hazards of
different  magnitudes and  for different sources (namely, soil, dust,  and/or paint).  It is the
Agency's intent that by helping to set priorities in addressing exposure sources, it will aid in
maximizing  lead  exposure  reductions  within  constraints  imposed  by  practical  resource
limitations.
Abt Associates, Inc.                           i                        Dnifti January JQ, 1994

-------
        With respect to paint, the Agency recognizes that a dominant pathway of exposure is
 through the contamination of dust and soil. Consequently, efforts undertaken to reduce exposure
 to lead in dust and soil can effectively reduce a substantial portion of exposure due to lead in
 paint, even without specific lead paint abatement efforts.  However, in those cases where the
 lead paint surfaces are in a deteriorating condition, there is an increased potential for both direct
 ingestion from accessible surfaces, and an increased potential for continual recontamination of
 dust and soil even with dust and/or soil abatement.  As a result, the Agency has elected to focus
 its paint hazard standard on the condition and location of the areas having lead paint.


 ES.3   PURPOSE OF THE ANALYSIS

        The goal of the economic  analysis presented  here is to help inform the  decisions
 regarding the specific choices of hazard levels to be identified under Section 403.  This report
 uses benefit-cost analysis to gain insights into possible hazard levels based upon the amount of
 lead in paint, soil, and dust and upon the condition and location of lead-based paint.  The results
 of these benefit-cost analyses identify optimal lead hazard levels that maximize the net benefits
 of undertaking lead exposure reduction actions.
 ES.4  SYNOPSIS OF THE BENEFIT-COST APPROACH

 ES.4.1       General Overview

       Benefit-cost analyses provide an orderly framework both for evaluating the impacts of
 a  specific hazard level and abatement strategy, and for comparing the relative  merits  of
 alternative levels and strategies.  A complicating aspect of evaluating the impacts of the Section
 403 regulations, both in  terms of their costs and benefits, is  that these standards do  not
 specifically require that any exposure reduction activities be undertaken as a result of their
 promulgation.  That is,  these standards do not themselves compel any public or private  entity
 to comply with the levels set. However, the Agency recognizes that these hazard levels will be
 used widely by federal, state, local and private entities to guide on-going and future efforts to
 manage the hazards of lead in paint, soil  and dust.   Therefore,  the Agency  considers it
 appropriate to attribute changes in the nature or extent of abatement to this rule. By following
 this approach, the Agency can arrive at a set of standards which, when acted upon by public and
 private entities, will maximize net social welfare.

       Because the Section  403 rules do  not mandate specific actions, it is not possible to
 analyze fully developed regulatory alternatives per se. Instead, an  approach has been taken that
 considers  what the benefits and costs  would be if some broadly defined abatement efforts  are
 undertaken for reducing lead in these  media.  These abatement alternatives attempt to capture
 the range of  some reasonable extremes of full-scale lead abatement  actions and exposure
 reduction  efforts conducted on a more limited scale.

       In  carrying out these analyses,  a baseline estimate was first made of the magnitude and
 value of the health damages that would be incurred by several generations of children assuming

Abt Associates, Inc.                            Jj                        Draft, January 10. 1994

-------
 that future exposure levels to lead in paint,  soil,  and dust are  not changed from current
 conditions. Against this baseline, analyses were performed of the residual damages that would
 be incurred if lead levels in paint, soil and dust were reduced to lower levels as a result of the
 broadly defined abatement activities noted above, -reflecting assumptions  made about their
 efficacy. The benefits of these activities were then determined from the difference between the
 estimated baseline damages and the residual, post-abatement damages.  These estimated benefits
 were then compared with the estimated costs of carrying out the various abatement activities,
 identifying the hazard levels generating health benefits greater than costs and, in particular, the
 hazard levels maximizing the net benefits to society.
 ES.4.2       Abatement Decision Rules
       This analysis considers five different decision rules under which homeowners initiate
 abatement.  It is assumed that this abatement is prompted by and takes place just prior to the
 birth of a child, in order to avoid subsequent exposures for the newborn.  These decision rules
 vary in the degree to which EPA's guidance, primarily in the form of hazard levels, induces the
 abatements.  At one extreme is a decision rule in which EPA provides no hazard levels.
 Instead, households are assumed to obtain perfect information about the benefits and costs of
 varioius abatement options for their respective homes and to undertake the one, if any, with the
 highest net benefits.  The decision rule is called voluntary optimum. It has the highest net
 benefits of all decision rules considered.

       This decision rule also serves as a benchmark against which the  other four decision rules
 can  be judged,  both in terms of net benefits  achievable and  the  nature of the  information
 households have.   Of course, a primary role of promulgating hazard  levels  is to provide
 households with information that will induce abatements where appropriate.  This objective is
 complicated by  the fact that there is a tradeoff between conciseness in the way hazard levels are
 promulgated  and the appropriateness of any  set of hazard levels  for a particular home.
 Conciseness may be an objective in the design of hazard levels to be promulgated because it is
 likely that the more concise the hazard levels are, the more accessible the hazard  information
 is for homeowners.  If, for example, EPA promulgates a hazard level of 2,300 ppm for soil, a
 homeowner with a  soil  reading above this level could take the  hazard level  as unambiguous
 guidance to abate soil.  However, it  may not be appropriate  for  all homeowners with soil
 readings greater than 2,300 ppm to initiate soil abatement.

       This tradeoff is considered in the other four decision rules evaluated in the  benefit-cost
 analysis.  These decision rules vary in the extent to which recommendations are made for the
 three different media - soil, dust, and paint - and therefore in the extent to which homeowners
 may be induced to take action. Under some decision rules, a recommendation is made for only
 one medium,  such as dust, and under other decision rules, recommendations are made for all
 three media.  Yet, the hazard levels  considered are all very simple.   The recommendations
 considered are ones which can be expressed as one set of numbers, such as one hazard level for
 soil  for all houses in the country.   While concise, such recommendations  cannot avoid
 introducing some errors in abatement choices since the recommendations are never exactly
 tailored to any particular house's circumstances.

Abt Associates, Inc.                            ft                        Drafti January I0i 1994

-------
       Under all four decision rules, a recommendation is made to homeowners to conduct
 abatement if lead-based paint is in bad condition. Under the first decision rule, this is the only
 explicit recommendation made. Under the second decision rule, a recommendation is also made
 to abate if lead exceeds a threshold in one particular medium.  Each medium is considered in
 turn, so that there are three examples under this decision rule - what happens if a hazard level
 for soil alone is promulgated, what happens if a hazard level for dust alone is promulgated, and
 what happens if a hazard level for paint alone (based upon the amount of lead present in addition
 to  condition)  is promulgated.   The third decision  rule examines the net  benefits from
 promulgating hazard levels for two media in tandem rather one medium alone. All combinations
 (soil/dust, soil/paint, and dust/paint) are evaluated.  The fourth decision rule evaluates the net
 benefits  of promulgating all three hazard levels (soil,  dust, and paint) together as well as the
 paint condition recommendation.

       For any given medium under a decision rule, a wide range of levels were evaluated in
 the benefit-cost analysis.  When more than one medium is combined as a set of candidate hazard
 levels, such as soil and dust hazard levels  under the two-media decision rule, the number of
 potential combinations is enormous.  All soil levels from 100 ppm to 3,000 ppm are combined
 as candidate hazard levels with all  dust levels from 100 ppm to 2,000 ppm.  However, this
 analysis  focuses primarily on the set of hazard levels that have the highest net benefits.  The best
 set for each decision rule is compared with the best sets  for all other decision rules.  In this way,
 it is  possible  to identify  the best combination of media  for which hazard levels could be
 promulgated and the best values those hazard levels  should take.
ES.4.3       Costs

       The cost analysis considered both testing and abatement costs for all three media. Unit
cost estimates were developed first and then applied to the relevant population in each decision
rule to arrive at total costs.  Each activity is discussed separately below.

Unit Costs

       Testing
       The unit testing costs for each media  depend on the number of samples taken, the
sampling method and the cost of analysis. Using the Agency draft testing standards as a guide
for the number of samples, the estimated unit testing costs are $230 for interior paint, $1 IS for
exterior paint, $138 for soil and $230 for dust.

       Abatement
       Abatement  unit  costs depend primarily on  the  activities involved.   Ten specific
abatements choices were considered.   These  include two dust  abatements  (recurrent and
nonrecurrent); two soil abatements (high-end and low-end soil abatements); two paint abatements
(high-end and low-end paint abatements) and four combined paint and soil abatements (high-end
paint with high-end soil; high-end paint with low-end soil; low-end paint with high-end soil; and
low-end paint  with low-end soil).  The components of each abatement scenario are shown in
Exhibit ES-1.
Abt Associates, Inc.                            iv                        Draft. January 10, 1994

-------
                                        EXHIBIT ES-1



                                Summary of Abatement Scenarios
Abatement Scenario
Nonrecurrent Dust
Recurrent Dust
High-end Paint
Low-end Paint
High-end Soil
Low-end Soil
High-end Soil and High-end Paint
High-end Soil and Low-end Paint
Low-end Soil and High-end Paint
Low-end Soil and Low-end Paint
Activities
Families moved off-site, hard surfaces (floors,
woodwork, window wells and some furniture)
vacuumed with a high-efficiency particle
accumulator (HEPA) vacuum. Hard surfaces also
wiped with a wet cloth (an oil treated rag was used
on furniture) following vacuuming.
Every ten years a thorough cleaning as listed under
nonrecurrent dust. Every month an additional
standard house cleaning consisting of general
dusting, vacuuming, cleaning bathrooms and wiping
window sills.
Full abatement of windows, doors, woodwork and
walls by removal or replacement and a high-end
dust abatement.
Replacement of windows and high-end dust
abatement.
Removal of six inches of top soil, installation of a
barrier and replacement of soil with new soil tested
under ISO ppm lead, resodding and high-end dust
abatement

Resodding including grading but no removal of
existing grass plus high-end dust abatement.
Combination of high-end soil abatement and high-
end paint abatement.
Combination of high-end soil and low-end paint
abatement.
Combination of low-end soil and high-end paint
abatement.
Combination of low-end soil and low-end paint
abatement.

Abt Associates, Inc.
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
        Two types of dust abatement were modeled.  Nonrecurrent dust abatement assumes a
  one-time high-end cleaning during which the occupants are moved off-site; hard surfaces are
  vacuumed with a high efficiency particle accumulator vacuum and wiped with a wet rag (or an
  oil treated rag in the case of furniture).  Based upon available information, the cost was
  estimated to be $750. In addition to being considered as a separate abatement, the high-end dust
  abatement was included as a component of both the paint and soil abatements as noted below.
  The second form of dust abatement involved an initial high-end dust abatement, as described
  above, followed by monthly routine house cleaning with additional high-end abatements every
  ten years. This recurrent dust abatement scenario reduces the dust level to 100 parts per million
  (ppm).  The cost of the  routine house cleaning was estimated to be $38 per month, repeated
  monthly. The present value of recurrent dust abatement, calculated over the fifty vear lifetime
  of the model, is $7,676.

        For paint abatement, the high-end level of abatement assumed full abatement of windows,
  doors, woodwork and walls, as well as high-end level dust abatement (see above).  The present
  value cost of the high-end paint abatement was estimated to be $10,500 per home.  It is assumed
  to be permanent and to render the home free of lead-based paint. The surrogate used to model
 low-end paint abatement was replacing only windows, and consequently was applicable only to
 those homes having windows with lead-based paint present.  As with the high-end abatement,
 the cost of one-time high-end dust abatement was also included. The unit cost (i.e., cost per
 home) was  estimated  to be $2,750, and the abatement was assumed to be permanent for the
 windows.  The effectiveness was assumed to be equivalent to reducing the dust lead level by
 8.6%, the portion windows contribute to total lead-based paint area in the 1989-90 Housing and
 Urban Development Department (HUD) survey results.

       The high-end soil abatement was assumed to involve removing the top six inches of soil,
 filling the yard with new soil having a lead level below 150 ppm, and resodding. High-end dust
 abatement in these homes was also included.  Soil with a lead level above 2000 ppm was
 assumed to  be treated as hazardous waste; thus, hazardous waste transportation and disposal
 costs were added. In addition, if the house had exterior lead-based paint, the cost of its removal
 was included because this abatement was needed to ensure the effectiveness postulated. The cost
 of the high-end soil abatement was estimated to be $7,998 if the  soil was not considered a
 hazardous waste and if there was no lead in the exterior paint. Waste disposal added $8,414 and
 exterior paint abatement added  $5,000 to the abatement cost. The high-end soil abatement was
 assumed to be permanent. The low-end soil abatement scenario assumed resodding with some
 preparatory work on the ground and was estimated to cost $2,860. It was assumed that the low-
 end  soil abatement results in a  post-abatement soil level equivalent to 500 ppm.  The low end
 soil  abatement was assumed to require repeated resodding every five years for a net present
 value unit cost of $7,493.

 Total Costs

      The total costs  are shown in Exhibit ES-2 for the five decision rules evaluated.  Each
 total cost has a testing and an  abatement  component.   The total testing costs depend on the
 decision rule and the number of media tested.  Testing takes place at the birth of the first child
 and total discounted testing costs over the fifty year span of the model range from $14.9 billion
 for two media to $24.3 billion for all three. The abatement costs range from $13.9 billion for

Abt Associates,  Inc.                           vi                        DmA Jmuary ]Q 1994

-------
                                                              EXHIBIT ES-2
                                            Total Costs for Five Alternative Decision Rules

'•
2.
3.
4.
5.
Decision Ruin*
Voluntary
Optimum1*
Paint Condition
Onlyc
Single
Medium
Pbu
Condition11
2-Media
Phn
Condition*
3«.
3b.
3e.
4a.
4b.
4e.
3-Medh Pliu
Condition'
Soil
(pom)
-
-
2.300
-
-
2.300
2.300
-
2.300
Dull
(ppm)
-
-
-
1.200
-
1.200
-
1.200
1.200
hint
(XRF.
rag/cm1)
-
-
-
-
20
-
20
20
20
Nonintact Paint
Abatement
Recommended
No
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Abatement
Costs
(S million)
13.196
24.668
21.344
29.646
25.013
31.903
28.689
29.991
32.248
Tealing Costs
(S million)
24.222
14.982
14.982
24.346
14.982
24.346
14.982
24.346
24.346
Total Coata
($ million)
38.118
39.650
43.326
53.992
39.995
56.249
43.671
54.337
56.594
Coata by Type of Abatement Chosen* ($ million)
HP

20.134
20,134
20.260
20.429
20.260
20,429
20.555
20,555
LP
26
3.517
3.442
3.462
3,567
3.387
3.493
3.551
3.438
HS



272

272

272
272
IS
1.992

3,475
1.420

3.475
3,475
1.420
3.475
RD



971

978

978
978
HP/HS









HP/LS

943

943
943
943

943
943
LP/HS



87

87

87
87
LP/LS

74
350
74
74
350
390
74
330
NRD
=^=
11,878


2,150

2.150

2,150
2.150
=^^™—
'Candidate hazard levels examined ranged up to 3000 ppm for soil, 2000 ppm for dust and 20 rag/cm1 in paint.
bEach home selects abatement (or no abatement) that has highest net benefits.
cAbatement is recommended for homes with more than five square feet of lead-based paint in nonintact condition, regardless of XRF level or net benefits.  Home
        owners choose the paint abatement method that generates the highest net benefits. Results are reported only for homes that exceed recommended levels.
dWithin the full range of individual soil, dust and paint hazard levels that could be set as a threshold for action, with no constraints placed on the other two
        media, the levels specified in the table maximize the net benefits. Results are reported only for homes that exceed recommended levels.
eWithin the fall range of individual soil, dust and paint hazard level combinations that could be set as a threshold for action, with no restriction on the other
        medium, the levels specified in the table maximize the net benefits.  Results are reported only for homes that exceed recommended levels.
fWithin the full range of individual soil, dust and paint hazard level combination that could be set as a threshold for action, with no restriction on the other
        medium, the levels specified in the table maximize the net benefits.  Results are reported only for homes that exceed recommended levels.
SAbalement Codes: High Paint(HP); Low Paint(LP); High Soil(HS); Low Soil(LS); Recurrent Dust (RD); High Paint and High Soil(HP/HS); High Paint and
        Low SoiI(HP/LS); Low Paint and High Soil (LP/HS); Low Paint and Low Soil (LP/LS); Nonrecurrent Dust (NRD). The abatement activities were
        described in Exhibits 4.1-4.6.

-------
 the voluntary optimum to $32.2 billion for the three media plus paint condition constrained
 optimum. The higher value of the latter is a result of households being required to choose more
 expensive abatements to meet the constraining criteria than they would have chosen voluntarily.
 The majority of abatement  costs of the constrained decision rules result from abating all
 nonintact paint. The total costs, including both testing and abatement, range from $38 billion
 to $56 billion.
 ES.4.4       Benefits
       The benefits associated with various combinations of hazard levels and abatement choices
 have been examined using the following three primary measures:

        •   Changes in the characteristics of the population blood-lead distributions for children;

           Estimates of avoided incidence of adverse health effects, specifically, avoided loss
       of IQ points, avoided incidence of IQ  <  70, avoided incidence of PbB > 25 /tg/dl, and
       avoided incidence of neonatal mortality;  and

        •   Monetary value of the avoided adverse health effects noted above.

       Exhibit ES-3 summarizes the benefits  for ten decision rule options. Included there are
 the nine options that are described above in which the hazard levels for paint, soil and dust were
 derived primarily from  net benefits considerations.  For the tenth decision rule, hazard  levels
 were obtained that would minimize an individual's risk of experiencing high blood-lead levels.
 The rule was designed to result in less than 10%  risk of blood-lead exceeding 10 /tg/dl, less than
 5%  risk of blood-lead exceeding 15 j*g/dl, and  less than  1 % risk of blood-lead exceeding 20
 pg/dl.   Setting hazard levels of 500 ppm for  soil and 400 ppm for dust (with paint in bad
 condition also inducing abatement) accomplishes the risk-based goal.

       It is important to  note that  the  benefits estimated here include only those that  were
 quantifiable given currently available data. These types of benefits are comparable to those that
 have been estimated for children in conjunction with other recent regulations aimed at reducing
 environmental exposure to lead. However, other potential benefits exist for reducing childhood
 lead exposure, such as avoided impairment of certain metabolic processes and possible avoidance
 of cancer.  In addition, benefits realized to the adult population from reduced exposure to lead
 in residential settings have not been included in the base analysis because  available risk
 information is considered weak in the risk assessment community.  These benefits are estimated,
 however, in the sensitivity analysis.

       The largest benefits overall are estimated to derive from the 500/4007- decision rule, with
 approximately $67 billion in benefits over the  full 50-year modeling time frame.  This outcome
 was  expected since the environmental exposure to lead is reduced more than under all the other
 decision  rules resulting  in the lowest post-abatement geometric mean blood-lead values  (2.45
 pg/dl), the lowest 90th percentile value (6.43 jig/dl) and the largest values for avoided incidence
 of IQ point loss, IQ  < 70, PbB > 25 /ig/dl and incidence of neonatal mortality.
Abt Associates, Inc.                            viii                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                                                       Exhibit ES-3
                                                            Summary of Estimated  Benefits

Baseline
Decision Rule:
Voluntary Optimum
Paint Condition Only
Single Media: 2300/-/-
Single Media: -/I200/-
Single Media: -1-120
2-Media: 2300/12007-
2-Media: 2300/-/20
2-Media: -/1200/20
3-Media: 2300/1200/20
2-Media Option to Minimize High
Blood Leads: SOO/400/-
Post-Abatement Population Blood Lead
Distribution Characteristics fog/Hi)
OM
4.06

2.52
3.82
3.78
3.32
3.82
3.30
3.78
3.32
3.30
2.45
OSD
2.45

2.70
2.47
2.43
2.39
2.47
2.35
2.43
2.37
2.35
2.2
Med.
3.91

2.40
3.72
3.71
3.36
3.72
3.36
3.71
3.36
3.36
2.56
90th ft-tile
13.30

9.47
12.55
11.99
9.81
12.55
9.67
11.99
9.81
9.67
6.43
Afoided IQ Point Loss
Total
0

1,912,011
319,818
490,626
1,316,456
321.631
1,402,677
492,439
1,318,269
1,404,490
2,751,452

Avg./Child.
0

1.34
0.86
1.16
1.94
0.86
1.98
1.15
1.93
1.97
1.58

Avoided Incidence of:
IQ <70
0

5,434
1,081
1,909
4,874
1,084
5.305
1.912
4,877
5,308
8,823

PbB>25
0

63,422
14,744
30,736
68,513
14,745
77,479
30.376
68.513
77.479
94.656

Neonatal
Mortality
0

0
48
48
48
48
48
48
49
49
75

Vahie of Benefits orer
FuD Model
Tbneframe ($B)
=^=^=;^=
$0.0

$48.2
$7.3
$11.2
$32.9
$7.4
$34.9
$11.2
$33.0
$35.0
$66.7
=^=^=^=
Note: Except for the monetary value of the benefits shown in the last column, benefits presented hen are for first model year cohort.

-------
        The Voluntary  Optimum rule elicits the largest benefits among those decision mles
 derived from net benefits considerations. The value of the benefits for the Voluntary Optimum
 rule over the full modeling time frame is $48.2 billion. Although the post-abatement geometric
 mean for the Voluntary Optimum at 2.52 jtg/dl approaches the value estimated for the 500/400/-
 nile noted above, its geometric standard deviation (GSD) of 2.7 is significantly larger than the
 GSD  of 2.2 for the 500/4007- rule.  This difference in the spread of values translates into a
 higher 90th percentile value (9.47 pg/dl) for the Voluntary Optimum rule and a lower incidence
 of avoided blood lead values above 25 /xg/dl. It is also noteworthy that the Voluntary Optimum
 rule results in no avoided cases of neonatal mortality, since this rule does not induce any high-
 end paint abatement (a necessary condition to obtain this benefit).

       As noted in the preceding section, the nine decision rules arrived at using net benefits
 consideration include the constraint that lead-based  paint in bad condition will induce paint
 abatement regardless of the XRF value.  Listed as Paint Condition Only, Exhibit ES-3 shows
 that this component alone elicits $7.3 billion in benefits over the full modeling time frame.

       Among the decision rules setting specific hazard levels arrived at using net benefits
 considerations, the largest benefits are seen for those which include dust at 1200 ppm among the
 hazard levels (i.e., -/1200/-, 2300/1200/-, -/1200/20, and 2300/1200/20). The total benefits for
 these  four rules range  from $33.0 to $34.9 billion, with comparable impacts on blood lead
 distributions, avoided loss of IQ points, avoided incidence  of IQ < 70, avoided incidence of
 PbB >  25 /ig/dl, and avoided neonatal mortality. Among these four decision rules, slightly
 higher benefits accrue for the two that also include soil at 2300 ppm.

       Of the three rules setting hazard levels that do not involve a dust component, the largest
 benefits  are seen for the two involving soil at 2300 ppm (2300/-/- and 2300/-/20). These rules
 have total benefits estimated at $11.2 billion, with virtually identical results for the health effects
 avoided.

       The lowest benefits among the rules setting specific hazard levels come from the single
 media rule setting paint at an XRF of 20 (-/-/20). The total benefits for this rule are estimated
 to be $7.4 billion. Note, however,  that the paint condition component alone is estimated to
 provide $7.3 billion, indicating that setting the additional hazard level at an XRF of 20 for all
 paint regardless of condition provides little additional benefit above that resulting from abatement
 of paint  in bad condition.

       Exhibit ES-4 displays the relative contribution of the monetized value of each of the
 categories of benefits based on the first model year abatements for each decision rule.  The
 relative contributions of the benefits categories are comparable for the entire modeling period.

       By far, the major contribution to the value of the benefits derives from the avoided loss
 of IQ points.  For all of the decision rules, this component of the benefits contributes between
 75 % and 90% of the value of the benefits.  The contributions of the avoided incidence of IQ <
 70 and of blood-lead levels >  25 pg/dl are comparable  for each decision  rule, generally
 contributing between 5% and 7% of the total benefits each.
Abt Associates, Inc.                             x                        0^ january JQ, 1994

-------
              Exhibit ES-4.  Distribution of Monetized Benefits by Category for

                                  First Model Year Abatements.
               1.1
               II
              ii
              c  •g
              »  2
              m  ;r
$3

$2
$1

$0
                                                                    Total Benefits
                                                                  Avoided IQ Loss
                                                                 Avoided Neonatal Ktortaity
                                                               Avoided PbB iCS
                                                             Avoided KLOQ
           Awoided IQ<70
                            Avoided PbB>fi5
                                            Avoided Neonatal
                                            Mortality
                                      Avoided IQ Loss
                                                       Total Benefits
Abt Associates, Inc.
                                                XI
                                                                             Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
        The most variable contributor to the value of the benefits is avoided neonatal mortality.
 Except for the Voluntary Optimum and the 500/400/- decision rules, the monetized value of
 these benefits is comparable, approximately $140 million for the first year.  For the Voluntary
 Optimum, neonatal mortality avoidance makes no contribution, while for the 500/400/- rule the
 value is about $220 million.  Excluding the voluntary optimum, the avoided neonatal mortality
 benefits as a percentage of the total are highest for those decision rules with the lowest total
 benefits, and highest for those with the lowest benefits.  For example, in the Paint Condition
 Only rule, the first year benefits are estimated to be about $890  million, and the neonatal
 mortality  benefit at  $138 million comprises about   16% of the total.   By contrast, the
 2300/1200/20 rule has total first year benefits of $3.5 billion, of which neonatal mortality at
 $141 million is only 4% of that total.  For the 500/4007- rule, where the total first year benefits
 are highest at $6.6 billion, the neonatal mortality is also highest among all rules at $220 million.
 However,  as  a percentage of the total, these benefits  constitute only about 3.3% for the
 500/400/-  rule.
 ES.5  BENEFIT-COST ANALYSIS OF ALTERNATIVE HAZARD LEVELS
 ES.5.1       Results for the Five Abatement Decision Rules

       Exhibit ES-5 presents the benefit-cost results for each of the five decision rules. The first
 comparisons made in this section focus on the net benefits of each decision rule exclusive of
 testing costs.  This orientation makes it possible to distinguish decision rules in terms of the net
 benefits of abatement. The final comparisons in this section integrate information on the testing
 costs necessary to implement each of the decision rules.

 Net Benefits Excluding Testing Costs

       The voluntary optimum clearly sets the standard for judging the performance of the other
 four decision rules. It generates net benefits of $34.3 billion before testing costs are considered.
 The net benefits of the voluntary optimum surpass those of the next best alternative by nearly
 $30 billion. More than 45 million homes undertake abatement,  a substantial number especially
 given the assumption  under this decision rule that only  homes obtaining positive net benefits
 initiate abatement.  Exhibit ES-6 shows that all but one of the abatements constructed for this
 analysis would be chosen. Nonrecurrent dust abatement is the leading choice, by far, and low-
 end soil abatement is a distant second.  All other decision rules entail at least two million more
 paint abatements, primarily because of the recommendation  to abate lead-based paint in bad
 condition.

       This conclusion is borne out by  the results for the second decision rule, which is based
 upon the paint condition recommendation. Net benefits are negative (-$17.3 billion) even before
 testing costs of nearly $15  billion are considered.  Virtually all of the 7.1 million abatements
 conducted under this decision rule are motivated by the assumption that all homeowners having
paint in bad condition will undertake  the best form of abatement available to them.  This
decision rule provides a telling example of the tradeoff between conciseness in the form that


Abt Associates, Inc.                            xii                        Draft. January 10, 1994

-------
                                                                                        Exhibit ES- 6

                                                                     Benefit-Cost Results for Five Alternative Decision Rides


2.






Condition
Condition

3b.
3c.
4b.
4c.
o meaia riuo uonaiuon
Ippm)


2,300


2.300
2,300

2,300
(ppm)



1,200

1,200

1,200
1.200
mg/cm*




20

20
20
20
Abatement
Recommended

Yes




Yes

Yes
($ million)

7,319
11,186
32,945
7,383
34,920
11,249

34,984
Abatement
Costs
(9 million)

24,668
28,345
29.646
25,014
31.903
28.689
29.992
32,248
(Exclusive of
Testing Costs)
(9 million)

(17,349)
(17.159)
3.299
(17.631)
3.017
(17,440)
3,017
2.736
Testing
Costs
($ million)
24,222
14,987
24.222
24.227
14,906
24,227
24,222
24,227
24^3T
Net Benefits
(Including
Testing Costs)
10,072
(32,336)
(41.381)
(20,928)
(32,537)
(21.210)
(41,662)
(21,210)
	 (21,495)
Total Number
of Abatements
(1000s)
45.166
7.063
8,069
15,602
7.164
16,197
8.170
15.702
16.297 |
Number of
Abatements with
Negative Net
0
6,686
7,164
7.114
6.786
7.683
7.266
7.216
7.684 |
Candidate hazard levels examined ranged up to 3000 ppm for soil, 2000 ppm for dust, and 22 mg/cm' for paint.
Voluntary Optimum:

Paint Condition Only:


Single Medium:


2-Media:


3-Media:
  Each home selects abatement (or no abetement) that has the highest net benefits

  Abetement is recommended for homes with more then five square feet of lead-based paint in nonintaet condition, regardless of XRF level or net
benefits.  Homeowners choose the paint abatement method that generates the highest net benefits.

  Within the full range of individual soil, dust, and paint hazard levels that could be set as a threshold for action, with no constraints placed on the other
two media, the levels  specified in the table maximize net benefits.

  Within the full range of individual soil, dust, and paint hazard level combinations that could be set as a threshold for action, with no restriction on the
other medium, the levels specified in the table maximize net benefits.

  Within the full range  of individual soil, dust, and paint hazard level combinations that could be set as a threshold for action, the levels specified In the
table maximizes net benefits.

-------
                                                                                Exhibit ES - 6
                                                        Distribution of Abatement Choices for Five Alternative Decision Rules




4.




Condition
2-Media Plus
Condition

3a.
3b.
3c.
4a.
4b.
4c.

(ppm)

•
2.300
•
•
2.300
2.300

2,300
(ppm)

•
-
1.200
•
1.200
•
1.200
1.200
(mg/cm*)

-
-
-
20
-
20
20
20
Abatement
Recommended





Yes

Yes
Yes
Number of Homes Abated by Abatement Type (1000s)
HP

4,160
4,160
4,186
4,221
4,186
4,221
4,247
4.247
LP

2,774
2.716
2,731
2.814
2,672
2,756
2,770
2,712
HS

0
0
74
0
74
0
74
74
LS

0
1.006
411
0
1,006
1.006
411
1,006
RD
0
0
• o
276
0
276
0
276
276
HP/HS
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
HP/LS
0
114
114
114
114
114
114
114
114
LP/HS
0
0
0
18
0
18
0
18
18
LP/LS
O
16
74
16
16
74
74
16
74
NRD
44,567
0
0
7.777
0
7.777
0
7.777
7,7i1
Total
45.166
7,063
8,069
15,602
7,164
16.197
8.170
16.702
16.297
Candidate hazard levels examined ranged up to 3000 ppm for soil, 2000 ppm for dust, and 22 mg/cm* for paint.
Abatement Codes
HP = High Paint Abatement
LP = Low Paint Abatement
HS = High Soil Abatement
LS = Low Soil Abatement
RD = Recurrent Dust Abatement
Voluntary Optimum:

Paint Condition Only:


Single Medium:


2-Media:


3-Media:
                     HP/HS = High Paint, High Soil Abatements
                     HP/LS = High Paint, Low Soil Abatements
                     LP/HS = Low Paint, High Soil Abatements
                     LP/LS = Low Paint, Low Soil Abatements
                     NR D  = Nonrecurrent Dust Abatement

  Each home selects abatement (or no abatement) that has the highest net benefits
 Abatement is recommended for homes with more than five square feet of lead-based paint in nonintact condition, regardless of XRF level or net
benefits. Homeowners choose the paint abatement method that generates the highest net benefits.

 Within the full range of individual soil, dust, and paint hazard levels that could be eet as a threshold for action, with no constraints placed on the other
two media, the levels specified in the table maximize net benefits.

 Within the full range of individual soil, dust, and paint hazard level combinations that could be set as a threshold for action, with no restriction on the
other medium, the levels specified in the table maximize net benefits.

 Within the full range of individual soil, dust, and paint hazard level combinations that could be eet as a threshold for action, the levels specified In the
table maximizes net benefits.

-------
  EPA's guidance could take and the resulting inaccuracies in decisions made about abatement.
  The  last column of Exhibit  ES-5  shows  the  number  of abatements  induced  by  this
  recommendation that result in negative net benefits. Of the 7.1 million abatements conducted,
  95%, or 6.7 million homes, would be expected to undertake abatement, because it has been
  recommended, even though it results in negative net benefits.

        This outcome is possible not because homeowners are making irrational decisions, i.e
  taking steps known to generate negative net benefits, but because they are relying on limited
  information relative to what homeowners  are assumed to have under the voluntary optimum
  Under this and all subsequent decision rules, it is assumed that the decision to abate is induced
  by exceeding one or more hazard levels and not by calculating the net benefits directly.  If
  homeowners had made the calculation, as  was assumed in the voluntary optimum, they would
  not have undertaken the abatement.  Clearly the results from  the second decision rule show that
  there is room for finetuning the recommendations made to homeowners in the form of hazard
  levels. The third decision rule adds one more dimension to EPA's potential recommendations -
  a hazard level for one of the three media (soil, dust, and paint) while  keeping the paint
  condition criterion of the second decision rule. Two of the cases under this single-medium rule
  single hazard levels for soil and paint, also result in negative  net benefits and have only slightly
  lower error rates than the previous decision  rule.  For soil and paint, 89% and 95%  of their
 respective sets of abatements have negative net benefits.

       The prospects for using a single hazard level for dust are more compelling  The net
 benefits of a dust hazard level of 1,200 ppm are $3.3 billion.  The number of homes generating
 negative net benefits is high, 7.1 million, but the number of abatements induced is also high
  15.6 million, resulting in  an error rate of 46%.   As  Exhibit ES-6 shows,  52% of these
 abatements (8 out of 15 million) entail some form of dust abatement only.  This proportion is
 lower than that exhibited in the voluntary optimum, where approximately 99% of homes choose
 some form of dust abatement, because of the high number of homes assumed to undertake paint
 abatement to comply with the paint condition recommendation.

       The fourth decision rule adds yet another dimension to the candidate  hazard levels
 combining them for two media rather than just one.  To satisfy recommendations based upon
 these hazard levels, such as the case where the soil hazard level is  2,300 ppm and the paint
 hazard level is 20  mg/cm2,  it is assumed that any homeowner whose home exceeds either one
 of these thresholds would undertake the best soil and/or paint abatement that makes it possible
 to go below any binding threshold (as well as to meet the paint condition criterion). Exhibit ES-
 6 shows the distribution of abatements that would be induced under each set of two-media hazard
 levels.  Under this decision rule, the versions including a dust hazard level are the only ones
 having positive net benefits before testing costs are considered. In each case, the optimal hazard
 level for dust is 1,200 ppm, the same as the optimal level for the single-medium rule.  However,
 adding one more dimension to the decision rule constrains household decisions enough to reduce
 benefits slightly.  The net benefits of either two-media rule involving dust are $3.0 billion. The
 optimal hazard level to combine with a dust hazard level is 2,300 ppm  for soil or 20 me/cm2 for
 paint.

       The fifth and final decision rule presents the best set of three-media hazard levels  The
 resulting optimum brings together the hazard levels identified as optimal in the single-medium

Abr AssociaKs, Inc.                                                         Jamary

-------
 and two-media decision rules - 2,300 ppm for soil, 1,200 ppm for dust, and 20 mg/cm2 for paint
 plus the paint condition criterion - but at the cost of lower net benefits. Adding a third hazard
 level to the decision restricts  the leeway in household choices yet again.  This lowers the net
 benefits by approximately 10% and 20% compared respectively to the best single-medium and
 two-media cases.

        In closing this discussion of the relative net benefits of different decision rules, it is  also
 useful to point out that besides their clear differences in net benefits, the voluntary optimum
 differs substantially from the other four rules in the number of homes abated. The four decision
 rules based upon  qualitative or quantitative hazard levels induce no more than 16.3 million
 abatements, of which 7 to 8 million have negative net benefits. The voluntary optimum leads
 to nearly three times as many abatements - more than 45 million abatements.  None entails
 negative  net benefits.  This finding raises the possibility that better decision rules could be
 created that are both implementable,  which is the advantage of the decision rules based upon
 hazard levels, and that lead to positive and substantial net benefits, which the voluntary optimum
 does. Since the information bases assumed for the first group and for the voluntary optimum
 differ substantially, it appears that creating a better means for conveying useful information to
 guide homeowners' abatement decisions could be a productive route for  improving upon the
 decision rules investigated here.


 Net Benefits Including Testing Costs

       The inclusion of testing costs does not alter the ranking of nine decision rules considered
 here  although it does lower the net benefits.  The voluntary optimum still has the highest net
 benefits ($10 billion).  All subsequent decision rules have negative net benefits.  The top four
 among these are based upon a  single medium (dust=1200), two media (soil=2300/dust= 1200,
 dust=1200/paint=20), and three media (soa=2300/dust=1200/paint=20).  The overall  net
 benefit of any of these decision rules is approximately minus $21 billion, once testing costs are
 considered. The three lowest-ranking decision rules all have in common that they are based in
 some way upon a paint hazard level.  The qualitative hazard level based upon paint condition
 criterion ranks seventh, the two-media  rule based  upon soil and paint ranks eighth, and  the
 single-medium hazard level based upon paint alone ranks ninth. These outcomes and the finding
 of significant  negative net benefits associated with paint abatement highlight the potentially
 significant influence of the assumptions made regarding the effectiveness and  cost of paint
 abatement.
ES.7  SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS
       The number of parameters considered in this report is limited to three items that had a
significant likelihood of influencing the policy-relevant outcomes.

       First, the report considers the impacts that using low and high unit cost estimates have
on the benefits and costs of different decision rules and their optimal hazard levels.  These

Abt Associates, Inc.                           XVI                       D^fi January 10, 1994

-------
  assumptions provide a basis for comparison with the "medium" cost estimates used in the main
  analysis. This basis establishes possible boundaries for the benefit-cost results and the estimated
  optimal hazard levels. While the low and high unit cost estimates used in the sensitivity analysis
  are not the ultimate minimum and maximum values, they were constructed to be representative
  of the lower and upper ranges of values observed in practice. As such, these unit cost estimates
  are probably appropriate for testing the boundaries of the benefit-cost analysis.

        The bounding exercise for costs indicates that the findings regarding optimal  dust and
  paint hazard levels may not be affected by a better representation of the distribution of abatement
  costs.  Dramatic upward and downward revisions applied simultaneously to all abatements did
  not change the optimal hazard levels for dust and paint. This does not however categorically
  rule out revisions in cost estimates which could affect the optimal dust and paint hazard levels.

        The sensitivity analysis does show however that the optimal soil hazard level could be
  susceptible to changes in assumptions regarding the costs of abatement. While the optimal soil
  hazard level held constant at 2,300 ppm for an upward revision in all abatement costs,  it fell to
  1,500 ppm when all costs were lowered.  Consequently, it appears that the evidence for setting
 a single hazard level for soil is not clearcut.  Instead, a range from 1,500 to 2,300 ppm is
 supported by the model when bounding cost assumptions are applied.

       The second focus of the sensitivity analyses in this report is the discount rate used to
 express the monetary value of future benefits and costs in contemporary terms. The selection
 of a discount rate is one of the most commonly debated features of benefit-cost analyses of
 environmental policies. A rate of 7% was used in the main analysis of this report.  An alternate
 approach, which has been used by the Agency in some other regulatory analyses, involves a two-
 stage discounting procedure that employs both 3 % and 7%.  The impact of this approach on the
 findings of the main analysis was evaluated in the sensitivity analysis.

       The  sensitivity analysis revealed that  the two-stage discounting procedure raises  the
 possibility of a wider range of optimal  hazard levels for dust and  soil than was implied in the
 main analysis.  The range for the optimal dust hazard levels  is from 300 ppm to 1,200 ppm
 The range for the optimal soil hazard level is  1,000 ppm to 2,300 ppm.  The current analysis
 cannot categorically support the selection of one hazard level for dust and soil from each  of these
 ranges. However, several things remain constant between the findings of the main analysis and
 those of the sensitivity analysis. The voluntary optimum is far away the decision rule generating
 the highest net benefits and the paint condition  rule typically the least (and virtually always
 negative). The types of decision rules that involve hazard levels for dust and soil that have the
 highest net benefits are generally the same under the two-stage procedure as they are in the main
 analysis. They are the single-medium dust rule,  the two-media rales based upon soil and dust
 and upon dust and paint,  and the three-media rale.

       The third focus of the sensitivity analyses in this report considers the possible benefits
 to adults and children already in the home at the time that abatement takes place.  The main
 analysis presented in this  report was based upon a model developed to consider the benefits to
 children from the time of birth until  the age of seven years from the abatement  of lead
 contamination.  Not only was the risk assessment  focused on this population alone  but the
 behavioral assumptions regarding lead abatement were integrally linked to the impending births

Abi Associates, Inc.                           xvii                       Dmft Januafy  I

-------
 of children.  This model structure reflects the fact that this population has been considered a
 primary target for measures to prevent residential exposures to lead-contaminated paint, dust,
 and soil. However, other populations may also benefit from lead abatement. This sensitivity
 analysis focuses on existing children in the household who are under the age of seven and on
 adults in the household.

       There are significant barriers to conducting a refined risk assessment  for these two
 populations.  Little is known about the size of the IQ benefits to these existing children who only
 partially avoid lead exposure during the critical seven-year period  of intellectual development
 since abatement was initiated sometime after they were bom.  For adults, risk assessment is
 complicated by the lack of information on the relationships between lead levels in paint, soil and
 dust and blood lead levels for populations over the age of seven.  For both populations the
 current model has shortcomings because abatements are triggered  by impending births rather
 than the circumstances of either existing children or adults.  For these  reasons, the overall
 estimates in  this sensitivity analysis should be viewed as illustrative only, in light of the
 unrefined and  somewhat arbitrary assumptions needed to generate the supplemental benefit
 estimates.

       This analysis found an optimal hazard level for soil of 1,400 ppm.  The optimal hazard
 level for dust was 400 ppm.  The  experience with paint hazard levels under this sensitivity
 analysis  reproduced that of  the two-stage  procedure,  where the  optimal hazard level was
 variously 4 or 20 mg/cm2, depending upon the decision rule, but the highest net benefits were
 based upon 20 mg/cm2.

       Taken together, the three sensitivity analyses presented in this chapter raise the possibility
 of a wider range of potentially optimal hazard levels than the findings in the main analysis
 imply. The optimal dust hazard level may be as low as 300 ppm or as high as 1,200 ppm. The
 main analysis found a dust hazard level of 1,200 ppm.  The optimal soil hazard level may be
 as low as 1,000 ppm or as high as 2,300 ppm.  The main analysis found a soil hazard level of
 2,300 ppm. In the main analysis and in the sensitivity analyses, the highest net benefits for paint
 were associated with a hazard level of 20 mg/cm2. Finally, a qualitative hazard level based upon
 paint condition typically  entails negative  net benefits with the exception of two cases:  this
 particular sensitivity analysis which linked supplemental benefits to paint abatement specifically
 and, the  shortest-term amortization case (10 years) under the two-stage discounting procedure.
 These two cases still seem rare enough to raise doubts about the desirability of a paint condition
 criterion given the paint abatement options constructed for this analysis.
ES.8  IMPACTS OF THE PROPOSED RULE
       Two types of impacts received primary attention in this report. The first set of impacts
relate to the regulatory flexibility of a rulemaking for Section 403.   Although no formal
regulatory impact analysis has been conducted, since Section 403 does not require specific action
to abate residences, this report identifies small entities likely to be induced to conduct abatement
activities because of Section 403 and evaluates the available data to quantify any effects on these

Abt Associates. Inc.                           XVlii                      Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 small entities.  Small landlords are the likeliest small entity to be affected.  Data on small
 landlords are not organized in an accessible form for a national analysis. Consequently, further
 analysis  of this impact could require resource-intensive data collection.   The second set of
 impacts relate to concerns about disproportionate burdens being placed on particular categories
 of households and individuals by actions under Section 403. These impacts were examined using
 socioeconomic information on a sample of homes and residents from the Department of Housing
 and Urban Development (HUD) survey of residential lead contamination that was a basis for the
 benefit-cost analysis in this report, as well as income information from the  U.S. 1990 Census.
 The results of this equity  analysis are discussed below.

        Existing lead-based paint hazards are a risk to all segments of our population living in
 pre-1980 housing. However, the HUD survey does indicate that some segments of our society
 are at relatively greater risk than others.  In particular, the residents of older, low cost housing
 are exposed to a disproportionately greater share of lead potential hazard than other housing
 units. The housing stock in the North-East (and to some extent the Mid-West) includes a larger
 share of  such units than other regions, creating a regional inequity in the prevalence of the
 problem.     Because poorer people   usually  occupy  low-cost  housing,  the   hazards
 disproportionately fall on lower income sub-populations (especially households living in poverty,
 with annual incomes below $10,000), creating an income inequity. Finally, the relatively larger
 share of African-Americans in the lower income groups results in racial inequity.

       Although the baseline risks from  lead-based paint disproportionately fall on poorer sub-
 populations, abatement may well be more likely to occur in housing units occupied by wealthier
 households.  Most of  the abatements under the Lead-Based Paint Hazard Reduction Act will be
 voluntary, and wealthier households are more likely to  have the means to abate an existing
 problem in their home, or avoid moving into a housing  unit with a known lead-based paint
 hazard.   An analysis conducted  for this report shows that income constraints could have a
 significant impact on the number of abatements conducted as the result of promulgating hazard
 levels under Section 403.  When abatement decisions are constrained by  income limits, the
 number of abatements undertaken falls substantially,  raising the possible dilemma that some
 necessary abatements  will  not be undertaken because of income constraints.

       However, determining the ultimate implications for equity is more complicated.  The
 abatements that are not affordable tend to be the ones that have negative net benefits. Although
 unaffordable,  such abatements are already questionable from the perspective of social welfare.
 Net benefits actually rise, and in certain cases become positive, when the number of abatements
 are constrained by limits on income.  This finding underscores how  any  policy  intended  to
 address income obstacles to abatement should be paired with an effort to fit  each house with a
 suitable abatement choice.  This analysis also shows that if subsidies were  used to enable
 abatements with positive net benefits that would otherwise be prohibited by income constraints,
 the funding needs could be significant.  Approximately $45 to $319 million would have to be
 spent  annually over SO years.
Abt Associates, Inc.                           xix                       Dmft January ]0, 1994

-------
 ES.9  CONCLUSION
        The highest net benefits identified  in this analysis derive from determining the best
 abatement for each individual home.  Once testing is taken into account, net benefits of $10
 billion are possible.  This approach, known as the voluntary optimum, takes the concept of
 hazard levels to the extreme since it is essentially equivalent to setting hazard levels for each and
 every combination of paint condition and soil, dust, and paint levels, among other factors.

        Among  the class of more feasible sets of hazard  levels, the primary candidate  for
 consideration is a single dust hazard level of 1,200 ppm, given the assumption that an additional
 recommendation will be made to homeowners that non-intact lead-based paint be abated.  This
 hazard level generates the highest net benefits among all of the alternative sets of hazard levels.
 Although the highest, the overall net benefits of this hazard level are negative (-$21 billion) once
 testing costs of $24 billion are taken into account.  Slightly lower net benefits can be achieved
 by combining this  dust hazard level with a soil hazard level of 2,300 ppm and a paint hazard
 level of 20 mg/cm2.  For any of these sets of candidate hazard levels it appears that the  net
 benefits are substantially lower because of the abatement aimed at non-intact lead-based paint.

        The support for these specific hazard levels is very consistent across different decision
 frameworks within the main  analysis but the range of possible hazard levels may be broadened
 once the results of sensitivity analyses or other decision factors are taken into account.  The
 sensitivity analyses indicate that the optimal dust hazard level could be as low as 300 ppm and
 that the optimal soil hazard level could be as low as 1,000 ppm.  The validity of these lower
 estimates hinges on the  weight given  to  the alternate  assumptions made in the  sensitivity
 analyses. Other alternative hazard levels besides those cited above may also be contenders if
 other criteria besides economic efficiency will be considered in EPA's decisionmaking.  One
 such possibility  is  to  choose hazard levels to  keep  the  risk  of exceeding a  blood  lead
 concentration of IS ug/dl below 5%.  This analysis indicates that taking this approach may be
 costly.   The net benefits of one such set of hazard levels (soil =500/dust=400) are negative
 (-$19 billion) before testing costs are included.
Abt Associates, Inc.                            XX                        Dmftt January JQ, 1994

-------
                                 1.  INTRODUCTION
 1.1    PROVISIONS OF RULE

        Section 403 in Title IV of the Toxic Substances Control Act (TSCA) directs EPA to
 promulgate regulations that identify lead-based paint hazards, lead-contaminated dust, and lead-
 contaminated soil.  Section  403 is one portion of the Residential Lead-Based Paint Hazard
 Reduction Act of 1992 (the Act), which requires that the United States Environmental Protection
 Agency (EPA), the Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD), and other Federal
 Agencies develop a national strategy to build the infrastructure necessary to eliminate lead-based
 paint hazards in all housing.  Clearly identifying what constitutes a lead-based paint hazard is
 an important step in encouraging effective action to evaluate and reduce the lead-paint hazards
 in the Nation's housing stock.

       The  Act establishes Federal grants  and other programs that create a partnership among
 all levels of government and the private sector in order to best  mobilize national resources to
 reduce lead-based paint hazards. Many of the activities involving the identification of lead-based
 paint hazards in the Act (including inspections and risk assessments by appropriately trained and
 certified personnel, as well as abatement of any hazards identified) are voluntary.  However, in
 certain circumstances the activities are required. Section 403 is consistently used throughout the
 Act to identify those paint, soil and dust conditions that are affected by the Federal and state
 programs included as a part of the national strategy to eliminate the hazards of lead-based paint
 in residences. Exhibit 1.1 summarizes the provisions of the Act that directly rely on the §403
 identification of a hazard.

 1.2    STATUTORY AUTHORITY

       On October 28, 1992 Congress enacted the Housing and  Community Development Act
 of 1992, which includes 16 separate Tides. Title X of that Act is entitled the  Residential Lead-
 Based Paint Hazard Reduction  Act of 1992.  Title X is composed of five subparts, including
 Subtitle B which amends TSCA by adding a new Title IV-Lead Exposure Reduction.  TSCA
 Title IV includes twelve sections, from §401 through  §412.  Section 403 - Identification of
 Dangerous Levels of Lead is very brief; the complete text reads  as follows:

       "Within 18 months after the enactment of this title, the Administrator shall promulgate
       regulations which shall identify, for purposes  of this title and the Residential Lead-Based
       Paint Hazard Reduction  Act of 1992, lead-based paint hazards, lead-contaminated dust,
       and lead-contaminated soil."

       The Section 403 identification of lead-based paint hazards  is used not only in Title IV of
 TSCA, but throughout the Act as the basis for determining the appropriate response to the
Abt Associates. Inc.                          1-1
                                                                      January ]Q

-------
                                                    Exhibit 1-1

        Relationship of §403 Identification with Other Provisions of the Lead-Based Paint Hazard Reduction Act
Section
 §101 l(a)
 Affected Housing Stock or Entity
 Affordable non-public housing that is not
 federally owned or assisted housing
 Relationship
 §403 Identification used to establish eligibility for
 receiving HUD grants for interim controls or abatement
 of lead-based paint hazards.
§1012
 Various housing receiving assistance under the
 Cranston-Gonzalez National Affordable
 Housing Act
 1) §403 Identification used to require reduction of
 hazards in course of rehabilitation projects receiving less
 than $25,000 per unit in federal funds, and abatement of
 hazards in rehabilitation projects receiving more than
 $25,000 per unit.
 2) §403 Identification used to establish eligibility for
 receiving federal funds  for interim controls or abatement
 of lead-based paint hazards.
 3) §403 Identification used to establish eligibility for
 including inspection and abatement costs in determining
 maximum monthly rents in federally assisted rental
 property.
§1013
Federally owned housing being sold
1) Housing built prior to 1960: Inspection and
REQUIRED abatement of lead-based paint hazard (as
identified by §403).
2) Housing built between 1960 and 1978: Inspection and
written notification to buyer of all lead-based paint
hazards (as identified by §403)
§1014
Low-income housing units under jurisdiction of
Cranston-Gonzalez National Affordable
Housing Act.
§403 Identification used to estimate number of housing
units in a jurisdiction occupied by low-income families
that have a lead-based paint hazard. Information shall
be used in preparing a housing strategy .
§1015
Private housing.
§403 Identification used by Inter-Agency Task Force to
recommend programs and procedures for financing
inspections and abatements.

-------
Section
§1017
§1018
§1021
TSCA Title IV,
§402
§1021
TSCA Title IV,
§405
§1021
TSCA Title IV,
§406
§1021
TSCA Title IV,
§408
Affected Housing Stock or Entity
Federally supported inspections, risk
assessments, interim controls and abatements
Sale or lease of all housing stock constructed
before 1978.
Persons offering to eliminate lead-based paint
hazards.
Information on identifying and eliminating
lead-based paint hazards.
Lead Hazard Information Pamphlet.
All executive, legislative and judicial branches
of the federal government having jurisdiction
over property, or engaged in activities that may
result in a lead-based paint hazard.
Relationship
§403 Identification used in Guidelines for conducting
federally supported lead-based paint hazard reduction.
Requires notification to buyer of any known lead-based
paint hazards (as identified by §403). Buyer has right to
perform inspection before being obligated by contract for
sale or lease.
Training and certification requirements for all persons
involved with identifying and eliminating lead-based
paint hazards (as identified by §403).
1) Clearinghouse and hotline to provide information on
identifying, reducing and eliminating lead-based paint
hazards (as identified by §403).
2) Establish protocols and performance characteristics
for products sold to reduce or eliminate lead-based paint
hazards (as identified by §403).
Required pamphlet to explain lead-based paint hazards
(as identified by §403) and approved methods to
eliminate those hazards.
All requirements in Lead-Based Paint Hazard Reduction
Act of 1992 shall apply to all federal departments,
agencies and instrumentalities.
Abt Associates, Inc.
1-3
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 existence of a lead-based paint hazard.  Section 1004(15) defines a lead-based paint hazaid as:

        "The term "lead-based paint hazard" means any condition that causes exposure to lead
        from  lead-contaminated dust, lead-contaminated soil, lead-contaminatedpaint that is
        deteriorated or present in accessible surfaces, friction surfaces, or impact surfaces  that
        would result in adverse human health effects as established by the appropriate Federal
        agency."

 This definition is repeated in TSCA Section 401(10), except the responsibility to establish what
 constitutes a hazard is clearly given to EPA;

        "...adverse human health effects as established by the Administrator under this Title."

 The proposed Section 403 identification of lead-based paint hazards is used throughout the Act
 to establish requirements and eligibility for programs dealing with the national strategy  for
 reducing the risks of lead-based paint.

        Section 1004 (16 & 17) goes on to define lead-contaminated dust as:

        "surface dust in residential dwellings that contains an area or mass concentration of lead
        in excess  of levels determined by the appropriate Federal agency to pose a threat of
        adverse health effects in pregnant women or young children"

        and lead-contaminated soil as:

        "bare  soil on residential real property that contains  lead at or in excess of  the levels
        determined to be hazardous to human health by the appropriate Federal agency."

 1.3    PURPOSE AND CONTENTS OF REPORT

       The purpose of this  regulatory impact analysis is to evaluate the effects of defining
 various lead hazard levels in paint, soil  and dust.  The primary impacts are the costs of lead
 abatements conducted in response to the regulation and the health benefits  that accrue to children
 from a reduced exposure to lead.  The report follows the standard outline for a regulatory impact
 analysis.  Chapter 2 describes past regulatory actions to  reduce risks from  lead.  Chapter 3
 details the method used to evaluate the risks to children  from lead exposure and explains the
 method for quantifying the benefits of reduced exposure.   This chapter also defines the market
 failure that indicates a need for federal  regulation, presents regulatory  options  that might  be
 considered, and gives an overview of the analytic approach.   The costs of lead testing and
 abatement are shown in Chapter 4 along with the total cost results for the regulatory options
 under consideration.  Chapter 5 presents the quantified benefits of the regulatory options. The
 benefit-cost analysis in Chapter 6 explains how the regulatory options were identified based  on
 the value of the net benefits and presents results  for each of the possible options.  Chapter 7
 presents sensitivity analyses to characterize the model uncertainties. The  final chapter (Chapter
 8) indicates the data available for evaluating the impact of this  regulation on  small  entities
 (businesses and governments),  discusses the regulatory impacts on  trade,  technological
 innovation and equity, and presents equity analyses for adults and children.

Abt Associates, Inc.                           1-4                        Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                          2. REGULATORY BACKGROUND
 2.1    INTRODUCTION

 2.1.1  Lead as a Public Health Problem

        Exposure to lead is one of the most serious public health problems currently facing the
 United States (ATSDR, 1988).  Lead's advantages, including its malleability,  resistance to
 corrosion, good insulation, and low cost, have made lead attractive for many applications; lead
 has been used in gasoline, ceramics, paint, and several other products. These uses have resulted
 in lead's release to and distribution in all environmental media, which has complicated efforts
 at reduction (ATSDR, 1988). Much of lead in the environment is accessible  to humans through
 a variety of exposure pathways, and since it does not degrade, continued use of lead results in
 accumulation in the environment.  Human exposure to lead is of concern because it interferes
 with the normal functioning of cells causing a range of toxic  effects in the nervous, red blood
 cell, and kidney  systems (ATSDR, 1988). Fetuses and young children exposed to lead are
 especially at risk from damages to the developing brain and nervous system (CDC,  1991).

       Knowledge of some of lead's negative health effects dates  back about  2000 years.
 Reproductive and developmental effects of lead were recognized in the 18th  and 19th centuries
 in the  United  States in female lead workers and  wives of lead workers.   These women
 demonstrated  problems  including  sterUity, spontaneous abortion,  stillbirth, and premature
 delivery, and their offspring exhibited high mortality, low birth weight, convulsions and other
 effects.   This recognition  resulted in  better  industrial  hygiene  which  in  turn, reduced
 reproductive problems (ATSDR, 1988).

       The prevalence of direct lead poisoning in children was  first examined in Australia in the
 1890s and  traced to exterior lead-based paint (ATSDR, 1988).  In the  U.S., physicians
 eventually defined lead poisoning in children as a clinical entity in the early  20th century after
 a  study reported that lead caused acute encephalopathy in a number of children. In the 1930s
 and 1940s,  epidemiologic data on childhood lead poisoning began to expand and accelerated
 through the 1960s.  Rudimentary screening of children in the  1950s and 1960s clearly showed
 that they were being exposed to excessive amounts of lead. Prevalence of lead poisoning was
 especially high among inner city youth.  More massive screenings in the 1970s resulted in the
 recognition of lead poisoning as a widespread  public health problem (ATSDR, 1988).

       Lead exposure's prominence as a public health concern has  been due to increased blood
 lead levels.  Although the average blood lead levels in the U.S.  population are estimated to have
 dropped  in the last two decades (U.S. EPA 1989b,  1991a),  levels are about 15  to 30 times
 higher in some U.S. populations than the pre-industrial average of about 0.5 jig/dl (ATSDR,
 17OO).
       The recognition of lead's adverse effects has resulted in lowering the blood lead level that
 triggers medical intervention. In 1970, the U.S. Public Health Service published guidelines that
 set the level at 60 Mg/dl  (CDC, 1991).  Shortly thereafter, the CDC set the guidelines at 40
 /ig/dl, then revised the recommendations to 20 jig/dl, and finally to  set them at the current level
 of 10-14 jig/dl in 1991.  Levels higher than this range trigger various intermediate actions; a

Abt Associates, Inc.                           2-1                       Draft. January 10, 1994

-------
 child with a blood lead level between  15-19  pg/dl should have nutritional  and education
 interventions; and a blood lead level greater than 20 pg/dl should prompt medical evaluations
 and environmental investigations (CDC, 1991).

        The following  sections focus on  regulations designed to decrease exposure to lead.
 Section 2.2 discusses laws and regulations designed to decrease exposure to lead in a variety of
 media, including products, releases, and past use of lead in plumbing.   Section 2.3 focuses
 solely on efforts at the federal, state and local levels to decrease exposure to lead remaining in
 residential areas (including lead in paint, dust, and soil).

 2.2    REGULATION OF LEAD PRODUCTS, ENVIRONMENTAL AND WORKPLACE
        RELEASES OF LEAD, AND LEAD IN DRINKING WATER

        Lead content in some products has been prohibited or restricted.  Also, environmental
 releases to air and water and in waste have been controlled. OSHA has set limits on workplace
 concentrations. In addition, efforts have been made to remediate exposure to lead already in the
 environment from its use in drinking water systems.

 2.2.1  Lead in Paint

        In the 1950s, the paint industry voluntarily restricted sale of paint with lead content
 greater than one percent (Mushak and  Crocetti, 1990).  Subsequently, the Lead-Based Paint
 Poisoning Prevention Act, enacted in 1971, prohibited the use of paint with greater than one
 percent lead (by weight of nonvolatile solids) in certain federally-owned or federally-assisted
 housing (HUD, 1990).  As a result of 1976 amendments to this Act, lead paint was redefined
 as paint containing more than 0.06% lead by weight (HUD, 1990).  In 1978, the U.S. Consumer
 Product Safety Commission banned both the sale of such lead-based paint  to consumers and its
 use in residences or on other consumer-accessible surfaces (16 CFR 1303).

 2.2.2  Lead in Gasoline

       The Clean Air Act of 1970 (CAA) first controlled the use of lead in gasoline because it
 rendered catalytic  converters inoperative.   In response,  the use of lead  in gasoline declined
 significantly during the 1970s.  In  1986, the U.S. acted to phase out the use of lead in gasoline
 entirely (51 FR 24606).  Currently, the U.S. restricts the amount of lead allowed per liter of
 leaded gasoline to 0.026 grams.  Effective in 1988, the United States also required all new light
 duty vehicles and trucks, motorcycles and heavy duty gasoline engines to  operate on unleaded
 gasoline.  (Unleaded gasoline is defined as gasoline containing no more than 0.01 g/1 of lead.)
 In addition, as of 1992, motor vehicle engines and non-road engines that require leaded gasoline
 are prohibited.  As of December 31, 1995, a total ban on leaded gasoline and  lead gasoline
 additives for highway use will be in place.

 2.2.3  Other Lead-based Products

       The U.S. canning industry has voluntarily phased out the use of lead solder in food cans
 since alternative, affordable processes for sealing the seams of tin containers are available (FDA,
 1992a). U.S. industry and the U.S. Food and Drug Administration have also undertaken efforts

Abt Associates. Inc.                           2-2                        Draft. January 10. 1994

-------
 to control lead exposure from ceramic ware (FDA, 1991), foil on wine bottles, and crystalware
 (FDA, 19925). Eight U.S. states have adopted legislation to limit the levels of lead in packaging
 materials (EPA, 19915).

 2.2.4  Environmental and Workplace Releases of Lead

        Under authority  of the Clean Air Act, EPA has established standards of performance
 designed to limit emissions of air pollutants  from lead smelting and processing facilities.  In
 addition, lead emissions from these and other industries are controlled via facility-specific
 permits written by states.  These permits are designed to reduce emissions to the extent needed
 to meet EPA's national ambient air quality standard for lead of 1.5 /tg/m3 (quarterly average)
 established in 1978 (43 FR 46246).                                                    '

        Under the Clean Water Act, federal effluent guidelines and pretreatment limits for lead-
 containing effluents have been established for over 20 industries.  These limits help achieve
 state-promulgated surface water quality standards (which may be based on water quality criteria
 published by EPA).  The  effluent limits are implemented by states through  facility-specific
 permits and, depending  on state water quality standards, may  be more stringent than federal
 effluent requirements.

        Releases  of lead as solid waste are regulated under the Resource Conservation and
 Recovery Act (RCRA).  A waste is defined as hazardous if, when tested, the leachate from the
 waste contains more than 5 ppm (40 CFR 261.24).  In addition, certain lead-containing wastes
 are separately listed as hazardous wastes. All of these wastes must be properly managed and
 disposed (40 CFR 260-270).

       EPA has also initiated a voluntary program to reduce lead emissions, based on the Toxics
 Release Inventory reporting. This project, called the "33/50 Program", encourages industry to
 curtail emissions of 17 toxic pollutants, including lead (U.S. EPA, 1992). The specific aim of
 the project is to obtain commitments from companies to voluntarily reduce emissions, effluents
 and off site transfers of the subset of the 17 pollutants that are applicable to their operations in
 two phases ~ 33 percent by 1992 and 50 percent by 1995 - using  1988 as the baseline year.
 As of 1992, 850 companies had agreed to participate in this program.

       Efforts to reduce exposure  to lead releases  in the workplace have included  setting
 permissible workplace air concentrations of lead and permissible blood lead levels in workers
 (Niemeier, 1991).  The  current Permissible Exposure  Limit  (PEL) is  50 jig/m3 for most
 industries except the construction industry (OECD, 1993). Under the Residential Lead-based
 Paint Hazard Reduction Act, passed in October 1992, OSHA is  required to issue interim
 regulations lowering the limit for the construction industry (ACELP, 1993).

2.2.5  Lead in Drinking Water

       Exposure to lead in drinking water has continued because of past use of lead in plumbing.
EPA has acted to reduce  these exposures through recent comprehensive measures (Mushak and
Crocetti,  1990).   In  rules promulgated  in  1991,  the  U.S.  EPA outlined  new treatment
requirements for drinking water systems (56  FR  26460).  The regulation requires tap water

Abt Associates. Inc.                          2-3                       Draft, January 10. 1994

-------
 sampling from high risk homes (e.g., lead service lines or lead soldering installed since 1982).
 If at least 10 percent of home tap samples exceed IS /xg/1 (the "action level"), corrosion control
 treatment and public education is required.  Replacement of lead service lines is required if
 corrosion control fails to bring water lead levels below the "action level."  EPA has also issued
 a maximum contaminant level goal of zero for lead in drinking water.

 2.2.6  Resulting Reduction in Blood Lead Levels

       These regulations and other efforts have clearly reduced exposure and blood lead levels
 significantly. Although no recent national study has measured human blood lead, it is estimated
 that average concentrations have dropped over the last two decades from about 15-20 pg/dl to
 approximately 5  pg/dl (EPA, 1991a).   In particular, reductions of lead in gasoline have
 contributed dramatically to reductions hi blood lead levels.  Several studies have specifically
 examined the relationship between blood lead and the lead content of gasoline, and have found
 a strong positive correlation (Schwartz and Pitcher, 1989, Rabinowitz and Needleman, 1983).
 Annest et al. (1983) noted a 37 percent drop in blood lead levels from 1976 to 1980 correlated
 with a reduction hi gasoline lead, while Schwartz and Pitcher (1989) estimated that as much as
 SO percent of blood  lead  hi the U.S.  hi the late  1970's may have been attributable to lead in
 gasoline.

       Reductions in dietary lead have also contributed to declining exposures.  Dietary lead
 intake for a two-year-old child has dropped from about S3 /tg/day hi 1978 to an estimated 13.1
 /xg/day in 198S; comparable declines have been seen hi adults (U.S. EPA, 19895). These trends
 are attributable to the reduction in gasoline lead emissions (and resulting reductions hi deposition
 of lead from air to soil) and the voluntary phaseout of lead-soldered cans by U.S manufacturers
 since the 1970s.  It can be calculated that these changes hi lead exposure from food have led to
 reductions of 1-2.S /ig/dl  in average blood lead levels (U.S.EPA, 1989b).

 2.3    EFFORTS  TO  REDUCE  LEAD-BASED  PAINT,   DUST  AND SOIL  IN
       RESIDENTIAL AREAS

       One of the largest remaining lead exposure sources for children is existing reservoirs of
 lead-based paint, dust and soil present in many residential areas (ATSDR, 1988). In an effort
 to  reduce exposure  to residential lead  hazards, regulatory efforts have been increasing  for
 several years to address these hazards.

 2.3.1  Current Estimates of Exposure

       Although new paint containing  lead was banned for use in residences in 1978, exposure
 to existing  lead-based paint has continued due to prior uses in residential and other buildings.
 In addition, leaded house paint can contribute to lead hi ulterior  dust and soil. There also
 remains a significant  soil burden of lead from leaded gasoline and lead smelter emissions.

       Several studies have demonstrated positive correlations between blood lead levels and
 lead in paint, soil and dust (Gilbert et al., 1979 as cited in CDC, 1991; Charney et al., 1980,
 Chamey  et al.,  1983, and Bellinger et al.,  1986 as cited in HUD, 1990;  Clark et al., 1991).
 Exposures are especially high in children.  In a 1988 Report to Congress on the extent of lead

Abt Associates, Inc.                           2-4                        Draft. January 10, 1994

-------
 poisoning in children, ATSDR stated that the existing leaded paint in U.S. housing and public
 buildings is "an untouched and enonnously serious problem" (ATSDR, 1988). The Centers for
 Disease Control conveys the seriousness of home lead exposure  as a contributor to elevated
 childhood blood lead by stating that lead poisoning exists in our society primarily because of
 exposure in the home (CDC, 1991).   However, since only about 5 percent of children are
 screened,  most children with lead poisoning probably are not identified.  Infants and toddlers
 are especially susceptible to lead in the home because they may ingest lead paint chips, dust and
 soil and because of the way they metabolize lead.  Older children, up to at least 8 years old, are
 also at increased risk (ATSDR, 1988).

        Exposure continues mainly from paint in older homes, since houses built after 1978 are
 presumed  to be free of lead paint.  A 1987 HUD survey of 284 homes built  before 1980
 indicated that, for privately owned  houses, an estimated 57.4 million (74%) of all pre-1980
 private homes have  some lead-based paint (HUD,  1990).   Of these units, an estimated 9.9
 million units have families with children younger than seven years  old. These units (with both
 lead-based paint and young children) represent 71 percent of all pre-1980 housing units occupied
 by families with children under seven.  Houses built before 1940  have the highest prevalence
 of lead-based paint in either the interior or exterior (90% of all pre-1940 houses), whereas 62 %
 of the houses built between 1960 and 1979 contain lead-based paint.  Of the homes with  lead
 paint, 3.8  million homes in which young children live have peeling paint or excessive lead-
 containing dust.

       A significant number of public housing units also contain lead paint. A small  survey of
 public housing conducted in 34 cities in 1984 and 1985 show that in housing built before 1950,
 81 percent of the units sampled contained lead-based paint, whereas a smaller proportion (48%)
 of the sampled units built between 1960 and 1977 had leaded paint  (HUD, 1990).  Preliminary
 results from the public housing portion of the HUD survey conducted in 1987 indicate a greater
 percent of public housing with lead paint (HUD, 1993); about 91 % of the sample of 97 public
 housing units investigated had lead-based paint somewhere in the interior or exterior of the unit,
 although many with  lead-based paint had fairly  low levels (HUD, 1993).  Families  of all
 socioeconomic classes may live in older housing, and thus be exposed to lead paint (ATSDR,
 1988). However, families with the lowest incomes are disproportionately found in older housing
 (ATSDR, 1988).                                                                   *

 2.3.2  Federal Regulatory Activities to Decrease Exposure to Lead-Based Paint in Existing
       Housing

       Federal regulatory  efforts and guidelines to limit exposure to  lead-based paint in the
 existing housing stock have evolved  over the past twenty years. The following two sections
 chronicle these activities in detail.

       The Lead-based Paint Poisoning Prevention Act and Amendments

       The Lead-based Paint Poisoning Prevention  Act of 1971  (LBPPPA)  and subsequent
amendments (1973,  1976, 1987, and 1988) have  resulted in a number of federal regulatory
activities to reduce exposures and risks from lead paint in housing.  In addition to setting limits
on the use of lead paint as  described above, the Act established grants for lead-poisoning

Abt Associates, Inc.                           2-5                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 screening and treatment, and required a report to Congress on methods of abatement (HUD
 1990).

       Abatement of Lead-based Paint Hazards  in Federally-associated, Public and Indian
 Housing. The 1973 amendments required HUD to eliminate, as much as was practical, hazards
 of lead-based paint poisoning in pre-1950 housing covered by housing subsidies and applications
 for mortgage insurance and in all pre-1950 federally owned housing prior to sale.  HUD acted
 by issuing  regulations to warn  tenants and purchasers of HUD-associated housing of the
 "immediate hazard" of lead-based paint (defined as conditions associated with deteriorating lead
 paint surfaces). A1983 court action resulted in broadening the definition of "immediate hazard"
 to include intact paint; this definition was subsequently signed into law in 1987. In regulations
 issued by HUD in 1986 and 1987, the construction cutoff date was changed from 1950 to 1973
 in most  cases.  HUD again changed the cutoff date in  response to 1987 amendments to the
 LBPPPA; the new date became 1978 for all programs (HUD, 1990). The 1988 Amendments
 to the LBPPPA specified the level which defines a lead paint surface as 0.5%  by weight or 1.0
 mg/cra2  (AECLP, 1993).  HUD  has also promulgated rules to eliminate lead paint hazards in
 public and Indian housing (Mushak and Crocetti, 1990).  In these types of units that have
 children younger than 7 years old, inspections for defective paint surfaces are required; if a child
 has an elevated blood lead level,  then the house must be inspected for chewable and defective
 surfaces, and abatement is required in dwellings, common areas, or public child care facilities
 within the public  housing.

       Grants.  The LBPPPA authorized funding for States and cities to conduct extensive
 screening programs  to identify  lead-poisoned  children, refer  them for medical treatment,
 investigate their houses for lead,  and require abatement (HUD, 1990).

       Research and Reports to Congress.  The 1971 LBPPPA required a report to Congress
 on the "nature and extent of the problem of lead-based paint poisoning" and methods of removal.
 Then, the 1987 amendments required an extensive research  and demonstration project on lead-
 paint testing and abatement technologies in HUD-owned housing, as  well as additional reports
 to Congress (HUD, 1990). In response to another mandate of the  1987 amendments, HUD
 conducted a survey of the distribution of lead-based  paint in the nation's housing stock and
 submitted a report on the results for privately-owned housing to Congress in a comprehensive
 plan for  abating  paint in private housing.   Additional  amendments in 1988 required a
 demonstration of  abatement techniques in public housing as well as a comprehensive plan to
 address abatement in public housing (HUD, 1990).

       Interim Guidelines.  In response to a need for better guidance on testing, abatement,
 remediation, disposal, and worker protection, HUD published interim guidelines related to these
 activities and issues in 1990; these guidelines were specifically related to the concerns of public
 housing agencies.  The guidelines have been used subsequently in the abatement demonstration
 in public housing  (HUD, 1990; EPA, 1993).

      The Residential Lead-based Paint Ha^rd Reduction  Act

      The most recent statutory  activity related to the reduction of lead paint hazards is the
enactment of the Residential Lead-based Paint Hazard Reduction Act in October of 1992. Also

Abt Associates, Inc.                          2-6                       Draft, January 10. 1994

-------
 known as Title X of the Housing and Community Development Act of 1992, this Act amends
 sections of the LBPPPA and adds a new section (Title IV) to the Toxic Substances Control Act
 (TSCA), in addition to other important new provisions.  Described as "the most comprehensive
 and significant lead poisoning prevention legislation in more than two decades" (AECLP, 1993),
 the Act aims  to provide  attainable goals for reducing lead hazards in residential settings by
 targeting specific housing in the greatest need of abatement (AECLP, 1993).

       Federalty-owned and assisted housing.  Title X allows for more targeted lead  hazard
 evaluation and reduction  activities  in federally-owned and assisted housing (AECLP,  1993).
 Whereas provisions under the 1987 amendments to LBPPPA indicated that any and all  houses
 built before 1978 that contain lead-based paint constitute hazards that may be acted upon, Title
 X provides a  more strategic approach to reducing the hazards from lead-based paint.  This
 approach involves requirements for risk assessments, inspections, and interim controls for pre-
 1978 housing  (targeted housing) and also requires deadlines for action.  Title X also extends
 federal lead-based paint requirements to all  housing that receives more than $5,000 in project-
 based assistance under any federal housing or community development program (in addition to
 the federally assisted and insured houses covered under previous Acts) (Section 1012); inclusion
 of these houses significantly expands the universe of federally-insured and assisted housing
 subject to lead-based paint related requirements (AECLP,  1993).

       Additional provisions apply to federally-owned housing being  sold (AECLP,  1993).
 Properties built prior to 1978 must be inspected and their condition disclosed to the prospective
 buyer. Units built before 1960 that  have lead-based paint (defined as priority housing) must be
 abated (Section 1013).

       Private housing.  Private housing  has received greater focus under Title X than under
 LBPPPA. Although states, local governments or common law still determine whether landlords
 provide safe housing, Title X includes several features to encourage evaluation and reduction of
 lead-based paint hazards in private housing.  First, Title X  formalized into law a grant program
 run by the Department of Housing and Urban Development for reducing lead-based paint
 hazards in low-income privately owned housing.  Grants awarded to state and local governments
 for this purpose include $47.7 million for 1992 and $100 million for 1993 (Section 1011). Title
 X authorizes an increase of $250 million in grants for 1994, to be determined by subsequent
 Appropriations Acts (AECLP, 1993).

       Other Title X provisions also affect  targeted private housing (AECLP, 1993).  These
 mandates  include integration of lead  hazard evaluation and  reduction  into local housing
 programs, and certain disclosure and warning requirements  to be met at the time of sale or rental
 of any pre-1978 housing unit (Sections 1014 and  1018). The Act also requires establishment of
 a national task force on lead-based paint hazard reduction and financing; this group is to be made
 up of an array of groups  involved in housing, real estate, insurance, lending, abatement,  and
 other groups (Section 1015).

       Safety of residents and workers.   This  law requires  promulgation of a number of
 regulations addressing the safety of workers undertaking interventions and safety of families who
 live or will live in treated housing.  Section 1021 amends TSCA by adding a new Title IV,
 which primarily addresses EPA requirements for contractor training and certification.   This

Abt Associates, Inc.                          2-7                       Draft, January JO, 1994

-------
 regulatory analysis supports the development of the regulation that responds to TSCA § 403 (in
 § 1021); this regulation requires EPA to define a "lead-based paint hazard" and dangerous levels
 of lead in dust and soil. EPA must also set standards of minimum performance for lead-based
 paint activities and  ensure that individuals engaged in activities are trained, that training
 programs are accredited, and that contractors are certified (TSCA § 402).  HUD and EPA are
 to assist in funding state certification and training programs and to issue standards for a model
 state program (TSCA § 404). In addition, EPA must assure that a program is in place to certify
 environmental sampling laboratories and must provide for development of products and devices
 for testing and abatement (TSCA § 405).  To further protect abatement  workers (and other
 construction  workers),  OSHA is required to issue interim final regulations  on the maximum
 permissible limit of lead in air at construction sites (§ 1031 and 1032).

       Education regarding lead paint hazards.  Title X also mandates  a  variety  of  public
 educational efforts. A hotline designed to inform the public about lead hazards was set up soon
 after passage of the 1992 Act. The National Clearinghouse on  Childhood Lead Poisoning was
 then established in April,  1993.  The Consumer Product Safety Commission, in coordination
 with EPA, is also developing educational materials such as information  to be displayed by
 hardware stores that  sell paint removal products (AECLP, 1993).

       Research and development.  A variety of research  is also required under Title X. EPA
 is required to conduct a study on the hazard potential of renovation and remodeling and must
 publish results by April, 1995 (Section 1021: TSCA 402).  The new TSCA Section 405 requires
 a study on the methods to reduce occupational lead exposures and a study of the sources of lead
 exposure in children to be issued as a report to Congress. Section 1051-1053 of Title X requires
 research and evaluation on various lead-based paint testing and abatement topics; five million
 dollars is appropriated for  this research  in each of the years 1993 and 1994.

 2.3.3  Federal Guidelines and Other Activities Related to Lead in Soils and Dust

 Guidelines for levels of lead in soil and dust

       As mentioned above, EPA is required to determine dangerous levels of lead in dust and
 soil under Title X. In the  meantime, however, interim guidelines for abatement of lead-based
 paint in housing set by the  Department  of Housing  and Urban Development recommend
 clearance levels for lead in household dust of 200 fig/ft2 for floors, 500 pg/ft2 for window sills
 and 800 /tg/ft2 for window wells (HUD, 1990).  No guidelines currently exist for residential
 soils, but EPA has adopted interim guidance for  levels to be attained at remediated hazardous
 waste sites. The interim guidance recommends soil concentrations between 500 and 1000 mg/kg
 (EPA, 1989a).

 Other activities

       Under authority of Title m of the 1986 Superfund amendments, EPA has funded projects
 in Boston, Baltimore, and  Cincinnati to test the  health effects  of abating  soil with high lead
 content in residential  areas.  This research  is being considered in developing the final guidance
 on soil clearance levels.
Abt Associates, Inc.                           2-8                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 2.3.4 State and Local Programs to Reduce Exposure to Lead-based Paint, Dust and Soil

       Activity to address lead-based paint hazards has recently increased at die state and local
 levels, although certain areas (e.g., Baltimore) have had programs in place for many years.  The
 following sections describe typical features in lead poisoning prevention projects and discuss
 notable state and local systems.

 State activities

       In 1991,  CDC issued  a policy statement on lead-poisoning prevention that included
 several recommendations. A survey was then administered to state officials in 1992 to determine
 their lead poisoning prevention and lead abatement activities and whether they had adopted the
 CDC recommendations.   States did not  respond to every  question in the survey.   For one
 question, thirty-seven of 46 responding states indicated that  they were coordinating prevention
 activities between housing and environmental agencies (Fischer and Boyer, 1993).  Nineteen of
 47 states had a program at the state level for monitoring health and environmental follow-up of
 children  with high blood lead levels.   Twenty-four of 28 responding states reported the ability
 to assure medical and environmental follow-up for more than 50% of children with blood  lead
 levels of 20 pg/dl and greater  (Fischer and Boyer, 1993).

       Several states  have  requirements and standards specifically related to lead abatement.
 Seventeen states have authority to require abatement or remediation of lead hazards and eighteen
 have adopted  abatement standards  (Farquhar and South, 1993).  At least twelve states have
 specific standards for soil (ranging from 100 ppm to 1000 ppm) and twelve states can require
 abatement of lead in soils (Farquhar and South, 1993; Mn Dept. of fflth, n.d.). Table 2.1 lists
 standards for paint, dust and soil adopted by several states; these standards represent levels  that
 trigger abatement or  remediation and/or levels that must be achieved during abatement or
 remediation.   In  cases where  abatement  has  been required, states have consistently ordered
 removal of paint  up to five feet from the  floor in order  to protect children (HUD, 1990).  The
 principal sources  of funding for abatement (as indicated by 23 states) have been local funds and
 money spent by owners of property with  lead hazards (Fischer and Boyer, 1993).  However,
 HUD grants for 1992 and 1993  are specifically slated for lead abatement in California,
 Massachusetts, Minnesota, New Jersey, Rhode Island, and Wisconsin (NCLSH, 1993; AECLP).

       Traditionally, state activities addressing lead-based paint and lead poisoning in children
 have not been extensive.  Blood screening  has been the primary program activity  of states,
 usually provided by walk-in clinics or special screening  campaigns. The extent of screening,
 however, varies widely because of budget constraints (HUD, 1990). Environmental intervention
 has often only occurred after identification of a poisoned child. In states that have authority to
 require abatement, the authority usually occurs through negotiation so as not to cause undue
 financial  hardship. In addition, states have not usually provided funds for abatement activities
 recommended as a result of medical and environmental intervention (HUD,  1990).
Abt Associates, Inc.                           2-9                        Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                      Exhibit 2-1
             Standards for Paint, Dust, and Soil Adopted by Selected States
   Massachusetts
0.5% by weight
      or
  1.2 mg/cm2
    200 (floor)
 500 (window sill)
800 (window well)
 1000
  by
weight
105 CMR 460.020;
460.170
     Maryland
0.5% by weight
      or
  0.7 mg/cm2
    200 (floor)
 500 (window sill)
800 (window well)
 none
COMAR 26.02.07
    Minnesota
0.5% by weight
      or
  1.0 mg/cm2
    80 (floor)
 300 (window sill)
500 (window well)
100 by
weight
Mn Dept of fflth,
1993
   Rhode Island
    0.05%
  or 500 ppm
 on non-intact
    surfaces
    200 (floor)
 500 (window sill)
800 (window well)
 1000
  by
weight
R 23-24.6-PB
       While most states generally have had limited programs,  Maryland and Massachusetts
have traditionally had more extensive systems (HUD, 1990). In 1972, Massachusetts established
the first statewide program. Subsequently, Massachusetts has had some of the highest screening
penetration  rates in the country (Prenney, 1987).  The features that distinguish both  the
Maryland and the Massachusetts programs include the following (HUD, 1990):

       •     Both states have a high level of interagency  involvement which provides an
             effective mechanism for policy development and implementation. Before formal
             legislation was passed, each state formed a policy task force representing a cross-
             section of agencies.   This multidisciplinary approach  was then written  into
             legislation in each state.

       •     Both states have methods of enforcing abatement requirements. In Massachusetts,
             property owners who fail to comply with abatement orders are liable  for actual
             and punitive damages. Under Maryland's real property code, tenants may deposit
             their rents in an escrow account held by the district court when landlords fail to
             remove lead-based paint that is accessible to children.

       •     Both states  provide some level of quality control over lead testers, abatement
             contractors, and abatement inspectors.  Massachusetts requires  training  and
             licensing of abatement contractors and  inspectors, and testing laboratories must
             be certified.  Maryland requires that  workers be trained in safe and appropriate
             abatement procedures  (MDE, 1992) and has established a training program
             employing private and public training organizations that are certified by the state.
Abt Associates, Inc.
                       2-10
                                Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
       •      Both states have loan or grant programs to provide abatement funds for property
              owners with limited resources.  Massachusetts has also established a $1,000 tax
              credit for private property owners doing lead-based paint abatement. (A new bill
              that has passed the Massachusetts house would increase the tax credit to $2,500
              (Carroll,  1993).)

       •      Both  have attempted  to  provide relocation resources  for  families  during
              abatement. However, the availability of suitable interim housing is a problem.
              The State of Maryland has given the City of Baltimore a grant for "lead-safe"
              houses to be used for transitional housing during abatement.

       •      Both states require that all cases of lead poisoning  be reported to the state health
              department.   Private physicians  must screen all preschool children for lead
              poisoning and report cases of children with high blood lead levels to appropriate
              authorities for followup. In 1991, a year after Massachusetts passed its regulation
              requiring screening of all pre-school children, the screening rate of children aged
              6 months to 6 years was 74% compared with 50% in 1989 (MDH, n.d.).

       •      Both states have legislation that calls for investigation, testing, and approval of
              new abatement  or containment technologies.  Maryland has been involved in
              ongoing research on the effects  of lead dust on blood lead in abatement workers
              and the development of testing protocols for encapsulation products.  Maryland
              has pioneered the development of standards and procedures for worker protection
              during abatement, dust containment, and post-abatement cleanup, inspections, and
              clearances.  These methods have provided much  of the basis for the National
              Institute of Building Science's guidelines for testing and abatement of lead-based
              paint in housing, which in turn, became the basis for the HUD interim guidelines
              (HUD, 1990).

       Rhode Island was able to draw from features of the existing Massachusetts lead poisoning
prevention and abatement program in addition to adding aspects of its own  (Vanderslice, 1993).
Rhode Island's Lead Poisoning  Prevention Act was passed in  1991.   Under the  law, the
Department of Health is authorized to expand blood lead screening to all children under six and
set up a public education program. Houses where children with  blood lead levels of 25 pg/dl
or greater have been identified must be inspected, and nonintact lead hazards in these homes
must  be abated (RTDH,  1993).  The Rhode Island  program differs from the Massachusetts
system by requiring comprehensive inspection of soil and exterior dust, whereas Massachusetts
requirements include only inspection of interior dust and paint (RTDH, 1993). Rhode Island also
generally requires less extensive  clean-up (i.e., lead does not need to be removed if it is  kept
intact within  the home) (R 23-24.6-PB; 105 CMR 460.020; 460.170).  However, a new bill
passed by the Massachusetts House would allow less expensive options for decreasing exposure
to lead paint (Carroll, 1993).

      Several other states have notable programs for reducing  lead-based paint  hazards.
California initiated  its activities in 1986  which included:   screening of children  in three
geographical areas, establishing a program to reduce exposure, reporting high blood lead levels
to the Department of Health Services, and submitting a policy report to the legislature on future

Abt Associates, Inc.                           2-11                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
lead poisoning prevention programs (Florini et al.,  1990). Minnesota was one of three states
(including Massachusetts and Maryland) to upgrade its lead paint abatement practices at a time
when the standard practices had not been changed  for 40 years (Farfel and Chisolm, 1990).
Other states, including Missouri, Louisiana, Vermont and New Hampshire, are in the process
of setting up childhood poisoning prevention programs (Farquhar,  1993).

Local Programs

       Local lead-poisoning programs are similar to state programs in several organizational and
programmatic features (HUD, 1990).  For instance, programs are usually located in the health
department. In addition, resources for carrying out local activities have been limited.

       Differences between typical state schemes and selected city programs lie more in the
extent than in the substance of the activities (HUD, 1990).  In general, city programs are more
focused and seem to receive higher priority, which may be due to the urgency of the lead-paint
problem in larger cities.

       In the Comprehensive and Workable Plan for the Abatement of Lead-Based Paint in
Privately Owned Housing (HUD, 1990), the Department of Housing and Urban Development
outlined several distinguishing features of local programs as determined by investigation of ten
selected cities:

       •     A city that is governed both by local ordinances and state regulations for lead-
             poisoning prevention and detection activities usually has local laws that are more
             stringent than state laws and may supersede the state requirements.

       •     In addition to providing intervention after cases of lead poisoning have been
             detected, local  programs may require  intervention  as  a result of targeted
             inspection or tenant complaints.  Several cities, including Baltimore,  Chicago,
             Louisville, New York, and Philadelphia, are authorized to take such preventive
             measures.

       •     In general, the city programs show more cooperation and coordination between
             agencies.

       •     City programs usually screen for high blood lead levels more systematically and
             target high-risk areas for screening.

       Under Title X, several cities and one county have recently received increased funding
for lead abatement. These localities include Boston, Baltimore, Cleveland, and Alameda County
in California  (NCLSH, 1993).  In addition,  other recent funding, authorized by the 1986
amendments to Superfund, has been given to Boston, Cincinnati, and Baltimore to evaluate the
impact of residential lead contaminated soil abatement on children's blood lead levels (Weitzman
et al., 1991; Cook, 1993).

       Of the childhood poisoning prevention programs on the local level, Baltimore has one
of the most extensive schemes. As early as 1951, the city banned the use of lead paint in the

Abt Associates, Inc.                          2-12                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
interior of residences (Mushak and Crocetti, 1990).  When a lead-poisoned child is identified,
the health department must be notified and the housing unit is inspected (BCHD, 1993). When
the city inspects a building and finds a lead-based paint hazard, a violation notice is issued to
the property owner, who must abate the lead hazard (BCHD, 1993).  Baltimore is currently
running a pilot program allowing alternative abatement strategies (instead of complete removal
of lead hazards) to make lead homes safe.  These strategies involve stabilization of identified
lead-based paint hazards, with complete replacement required only for windows and certain
surfaces in poor condition.  Dust samples are taken for two years after stabilization.

2.3.5  Benefits of Defining a Lead Standard for Faint, Dust, and Soil

       Although several states and localities have taken action on lead-based paint, many have
no standards for paint, dust, and soil abatement (nor standards for any one of the three media).
In addition, of the states and local areas that do have standards, the level of paint, dust, and soil
considered unacceptable differs among states. By providing definitions at die federal level for
lead paint hazards and dangerous levels of lead in dust and soil, those states that do not have
standards may be prompted to adopt standards more quickly.  In addition, the federal guidelines
will provide consistency between the states.
Abi Associates, Inc.                           2-13                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 2.4   REFERENCES
 Alliance to End Childhood Lead Poisoning (AECLP). 1993. Understanding Title X:  A
       Practical Guide to the Residential Lead-based Paint Hazard  Reduction Act of 1992.
       AECLP, Washington, DC.  January.

 Annest, J., Piikel, J., Makuc, D., Neese, J. Bayes, D., and M. Kovar.  1983.  Chronological
       trend in blood lead levels between 1976 and 1980. New England Journal of Medicine
       308:1373-1377.

 Baltimore City Health Department (BCHD).  1993.  Personal communication between Abt
       Associates and Michael Wojtowycz, November 2.

 Carroll, M.  1993.  Easing law on lead paint approved.  The Boston Globe,  p. 35.  July.

 Centers for Disease Control (CDC).   1991.  Preventing Lead Poisoning in Young Children.
       U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, Public Health Service. Atlanta, GA.
       October.

 Clark, S., R. Bomschein, P. Succop, S. Roda, and B. Peace. 1991.  Urban lead exposures of
       children in Cincinnati, Ohio.   Chemical Speciation and Bioavailability, 3(3): 163-171.

 Farfel, M.R. and J.J. Chisolm, Jr. 1990. Health and environmental outcomes of traditional and
       modified practices for abatement of residential lead-based paint.  American Journal of
       Public Health, 80 (10): 1240-1245.

 Farquhar, D.   1993. Personal Communication with Doug Farquhar, National Conference of
       State Legislatures.  September 30.

 Farquhar, D. and L. South.  1993.  Lead Poisoning Prevention:  Directory of State Contacts
       1993.  National Council of State Legislatures.  Denver, CO.  May.

 Fischer, D.B. and A. Boyer.  1993.  State activities  for prevention of lead poisoning among
       children-United States, 1992.  Journal of American Medical Association, 269(13)-1614-
       1616.

 Florini, K.L.,  G.D. Krumbhaar, and E.K. Silbergeld.  1990.  Legacy of Lead:  America's
       Continuing Epidemic of Childhood Lead Poisoning.  Environmental Defense Fund,
       Washington, DC. March.

 Maryland  Department of the Environment (MDE), Division of Lead Poisoning  Prevention.
       1992.  Lead Paint Hazard Fact Sheet #1:  The abatement of lead paint hazards.  June.

Maryland Department of the Environment (MDE).  1988. COMAR 26.02.07:  Procedures for
       Abating Lead Containing Substances From Buildings. August  8.
Abt Associates, Inc.                         2-14                      Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 Massachusetts Department of Health (MDH), Childhood Lead Poisoning Prevention Program.
        n.d. Statement describing the Massachusetts response to the 1991 CDC Statement.

 Massachusetts Department of Public Health. 1992. 105 Code of Massachusetts 460.000: Lead
        Poisoning Prevention and Control.  April.

 Minnesota Department of Health (Mn Dept. fflth).  n.d.  Summary of Rules Governing Lead
        Abatement Methods and Standards for Lead in Paint, Dust, Drinking Water  and Bare
        Soil.

 Mushak, P., and A. Crocetti. 1990.  Methods for reducing lead exposure in young children and
        other risk groups: an integrated summary of a report to the U.S. Congress on childhood
        lead poisoning.  Environmental Health Perspectives, 89:125-135.

 Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD).  1993.  Risk Reduction
       Monograph No. 1:  Lead.  Background and National Experience with Reducing Risk.
       Paris: Environment Directorate, OECD. Document No. OCDE/GD(93)67.

 Prenney, B.  1987. The Massachusetts lead program: moving toward phase 2.  Prevention
       Update. Developed by the Maternal and Child Health Consortium Project of AAUAP
       and the National Coalition on Prevention of Mental Retardation. April.

 Rabinowitz, M. and H. Needleman.  1983.  Petrol lead sales and umbilical cord blood lead
       levels in Boston, MA.  Lancet, 8314/5 (1):63.

 Rhode Island Department of Health (RIDH).  1993.  Personal communication between Abt
       Associates and Bob Vanderslice, Chief of the Office of Environmental Health Risk
       Assessment, October 28.

 Rhode Island Department of Health.  1993. R 23-24.6-PB: Rules and Regulations for Lead
       Poisoning Prevention.

 Schwartz, J. and H. Pitcher.  1989.  The relationship between gasoline lead and blood lead in
       the United States. Journal of Official Statistics, 5:421-431.

 U.S. Department  of Health and Human Services, Public Health Service, Agency for Toxic
       Substances and Disease Registry (ATSDR).  1988.  The Nature and Extent of Lead
       Poisoning in the United States:  A Report to Congress.  July.

 U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, Public Health Service, Centers for Disease
       Control (CDC). 1991. Strategic Plan for the Elimination of Childhood Lead Poisoning.
       February.

 U.S. Department  of Health and Human Services, Public Health  Service,  Food and Drug
       Administration (FDA).  1991. Fact Sheet: Lead in China Dishes Lawsuit in California;
       Lead in Solder Used in Cans, Crystal, and Food Wrappers.   November 18.


Abt Associates, Inc.                         2-15                     Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 U.S. Department of Health  and Human Services, Public Health Service, Food and Drug
       Administration (FDA).  1992a.   Personal communication with Dr. Michael Bolger,
       February, 1992.

 U.S. Department of Health  and Human Services, Public Health Service, Food and Drug
       Administration (FDA). 1992b. Statement by Michael R. Taylor, Deputy Commissioner
       for Policy, Food and Drug Administration, Public Health Service, Department of Health
       and Human Services Before the Ad Hoc Subcommittee on Consumer and Environmental
       Affairs, Committee on Government Affairs, U.S. Senate.  March 27.

 U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD). 1990.   Comprehensive  and
       Workable Plan for the Abatement of Lead-Based Paint in Privately Owned Housing:
       Report to Congress. Washington, DC. December.

 U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD).  1993. Personal Communication
       with Steven Weitz.  September 29.

 U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA).  1989a. Interim Guidance on Establishing Soil
       Lead Cleanup Levels at Superfund Sites.   Office of Solid Waste and Emergency
       Response.  OSWER Directive Number 9355.4-02.

 U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA).  1989b.  Review of the National Ambient  Air
       Quality Standards for lead: Exposure Analysis Methodology and Validation.  Office of
       Air Quality Planning and Standards.  Research Triangle Park, N.C.  June.

 U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA).  1991a. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency
       Strategy for Reducing Lead Exposures.  February 21.

 U.S. Environmental Protection Agency  (EPA).   1991b.   Summary of Public Comments:
       Comprehensive Review of Lead in the Environment  under TSCA.   November  22.
       Prepared for the Chemical Control Division, Office of Pesticides and Toxic Substances.
       Prepared by AMS, Inc. Contract Number TV-82228V, Subcontract Agreement No. 6,
       Task 2.

 U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA).  1992.  EPA's 33/50 Program Second Progress
       Report: Reducing Risks Through Voluntary Action. Office of Pollution Prevention and
       Toxics. TS-792A. February.

 U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA).  1993. Personal Communication with Brian
       Cook.  June 18.

 Weitzman, M.,etal. 1991.  Boston Lead-in-soil/Lead Free Kids Demonstration Project. Draft.
Abt Associates, Inc.                          2-16                      Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
              3.  PROBLEM DEFINITION AND REGULATORY OPTIONS
 This chapter characterizes the lead contamination problem to be addressed under Section 403
 and presents a rationale for government intervention. A risk summary, provided in the first
 part of this chapter, presents quantitative estimates of exposures, blood lead distributions, and
 incidences of adverse health effects.  The second part of this chapter presents an evaluation of
 the market failure associated with these residential lead risks, the need for federal regulation,
 and a discussion of possible regulatory option.
 3.1   RISK SUMMARY

       This section describes the risk assessment modeling procedures, information sources,
 and assumptions used to estimate the incidence of adverse health effects to children resulting
 from exposure to lead  present in paint, soil and dust in residential settings.   This  risk
 assessment model is used to support the Section 403 impact analysis by determining both the
 baseline incidence of health damages expected in the absence of actions  induced by Section
 403, and the benefits that will result from various exposure reduction actions that may result
 from the implementation of Section 403 rules.

       The risk assessment model has three major components:

       •   Characterization of lead exposure from residential paint, soil and dust;

       •   Calculation of blood lead distributions resulting from these exposures; and

       •   Prediction of the incidence of adverse  health   effects  from  the  blood  lead
          distributions.

       Each  of these components of the risk assessment model is  discussed later in  this
 chapter.  First, however, it is important to discuss some of the key underlying assumptions and
 premises for the risk assessment model.

       In this analysis, it is recognized that  the presence of lead in paint, soil and dust  is a
 long-term environmental problem.  Even though lead paint has not been used for residential
 purposes since 1979, and major historical sources of lead deposition to soil such as automotive
 emissions from leaded gasoline  have been eliminated or  severely  curtailed, the existing stock
 of lead in paint, soil and dust from these past sources will remain a major source of exposure
 to children  for  many generations.   Consequently, the risk assessment model  has been
 constructed to address not only the exposure and health risks to those children currently living
 in lead-contaminated homes, but also the risks that children who are born into these homes
 over the next several decades will face if abatement actions are not taken.
Abi Associates. Inc.                            3-1                         Draft. January 10.1994

-------
        To incoiporate this consideration, the risk assessment model is built around the concept
 of annual cohorts of children being born into homes over a SO year period, beginning in 1994.
 Based on Census Bureau population projections and other assumptions, the model incorporates
 estimates of the number of homes and births expected for each year of this time frame.  It is
 convenient to view the modeling conceptually as involving an iterative, stepwise process where
 separate calculations are made of the incidence of adverse effects for each of these SO annual
 cohorts of children,  which are then summed to obtain the total for the full modeling period.
 Computationally,  however, the modeling process  involves instead  a determination of the
 incidence of these adverse effects for the cohort of children born in first year the modeling
 time frame.  This result is then "multiplied"  using factors reflecting birth rates over the SO
 year period and the changes in the housing stock characteristics to obtain the incidence for all
 children born  over  the  full modeling time frame.  Results for  individual  years are not,
 however, explicitly isolated.

        Because of this modeling procedure, most of the Risk Summary discussion focuses on
 the first year of the model, which as noted above has been set at 1994.  In Section 3.1.4, the
 derivation of the factors  used to multiply the first year results to the full 50 year time frame
 are presented.

        The terms "baseline" and "first model  year" are used throughout this section.  These
 are not synonymous  terms.  The  term "baseline" refers to the analyses of exposure and
 incidence of adverse effects assuming there are no Section 403-induced changes. Subsequent
 analyses are performed  in which it  is assumed  that different  types of exposure reduction
 actions are  induced by  Section 403, and the results  of these are then compared with this
 baseline.  "First model year" simply refers to the results of either the baseline analysis or the
 alternative exposure assumption analyses for the first model  year cohort.  In all cases, these
 first model year impacts  are computed, and those results are then extrapolated to the full 50
 year modeling time frame through the use of multipliers, as noted previously.

       It is important to note that the baseline analysis reflects an assumption that no specific
 abatement actions will be performed to reduce  current and future exposure to lead from paint,
 soil, and dust in the absence of promulgated Section 403 regulations.  As discussed later,  the
 risk assessment model does include assumptions regarding the disappearance of older homes
 over  time, which has the effect of reducing the probability  that a child will be born into a
 home with lead paint in future years.  However, in the baseline hazard assessment analysis, it
 is assumed that no abatements of lead paint, soil or dust will be performed in  the absence of
 Section 403 regulations.   This is obviously  not the case, since many states and municipalities
 are currently implementing lead abatement programs.  However, it is difficult to estimate how
 many such abatements will be done over the next several decades.

       The "no  abatement" assumption for the baseline clearly results in an overestimate of the
 damages expected in the absence of the Section 403  rule as well  as the benefits of having the
 rule.  Nevertheless, using the "no abatement" assumption in the  baseline provides a common
 basis  for comparing the effectiveness of alternative hazard levels, and it is not expected to
Abt Associates, Inc.                            3-2                         Draft, January 10.1994

-------
 affect the  outcome of the analysis in terms of identifying the range of hazard levels that
 maximize net benefits.
 3.1.1  Characterization of Exposure

       The purpose of the exposure characterization component of the model is to define the
 distribution of lead levels in paint, soil, and dust in privately-owned housing stock in the US.
 The exposure assessment also addresses other characteristics of these  homes that affect
 children's exposure, particularly the condition of the lead paint.
       The distribution of current lead levels in paint, soil and dust in the US housing stock is
 derived from the results of the survey sponsored by the US Department of Housing and Urban
 Development.  That survey was conducted in 1989-1990 to provide better estimates of the
 extent of lead paint hazards in the Nation's private housing stock.  The results  of that survey
 have been detailed by HUD in its December 1990 Report to Congress entitled Comprehensive
 and Workable Plan for the Abatement of Lead-Based Paint in Privately  Owned Housing
 (HUD, 1991).

       The HUD survey focused on privately-owned, occupied homes  built prior to 1980.
 HUD estimated that at the time its survey was conducted,  there were approximately 77 million
 pre-1980 homes in the US.  The focus of the HUD survey on pre-1980 homes reflects the ban
 on the use of lead-based paint for residential purposes in 1978 by the Consumer Product Safety
 Commission acting under the authority of the Consumer Product Safety Act.

       There were a total of 284 homes sampled in the HUD survey.  The survey  sample
 design involved  a stratification of the pre-1980 housing stock into six groups reflecting three
 construction-period categories (pre-1940, 1940-1959, and 1960-1979) and two dwelling types
 (single family and multifamily).  To adjust for disproportionate sampling within these six
 strata,  as well as to correct for recognized disproportionate sampling with  respect to census
 region and presence/absence  of children under age 7, the 284 HUD  samples were given
 "weights" by  HUD so  that the results from the 284  samples could be extrapolated to the
 national total of 77 million pre-1980 homes.  These HUD-specified weights were used in the
 risk  assessment  modeling performed  here, with  additional adjustments made to them as
 described later to accommodate the post-1980 housing stock.

       Lead measurements of interior and exterior paint, exterior soil, and  interior dust were
 taken at each of the 284 HUD sample homes.  Generally, measurements of lead in these media
 were made at several locations and surfaces in each sample home.  Other information relevant
 to assessing exposure to lead in these homes was also obtained, such as  the  existence  and
 extent  of damaged surface area of paint.  The  following briefly describes how these HUD
 measurement data were used to characterize exposure potential in the model.

       Lead in  Paint.  The most commonly  used method to  measure the level of lead on
       painted surfaces in homes is the XRF (x-ray fluorescence) technique, which measures
       lead in paint present on surfaces in units of mg/cm2.  It should be noted that because of


Abt Associates. Inc.                            3-3                        Draft. January 10,1994

-------
       limitations in this analytical method,  low levels of  lead paint reported  by XRF
       measurements (for example, in the range of approximately 1.0 mg/cm2 or less) are
       considered much less reliable than are higher readings. For the purposes of this model,
       XRF readings of 0.7 mg/cm2 were used as the cut-off to distinguish between homes
       with and without lead based paint.  That is, homes having reported XRF measurements
       of 0.6 mg/cm2 or lower were considered to be free of lead paint.

       Exposure to lead paint in the risk assessment model is associated primarily with interior
       lead paint levels. In the HUD survey, interior  XRF readings were taken at several
       locations in each home, including one randomly selected wet room (i.e., rooms having
       plumbing such as  a kitchen or bathroom) and one randomly  selected  dry room.
       Measurements were made on several substrates  within those rooms, such as walls,
       ceilings, windows, molding, door systems, and shelves.  The value used to characterize
       paint exposure potential in homes was the maximum interior XRF value, which is the
       most frequently used measure to characterize lead paint levels in homes.

       Data were also obtained on the XRF value for exterior paint.  This information was
       used in the model mainly in  the abatement cost analysis to identify  those homes
       undertaking soil abatement that would also require exterior paint abatement to be fully
       effective. Exterior lead paint information was also used in conjunction with the interior
       paint  reading to identify the number  of lead-free homes in the HUD sample.  As
       discussed later, this information was needed to adjust the weighting factors to simulate
       changes hi future characteristics of the housing stock.

       The HUD survey also provided information on the condition of the lead paint in these
       homes. For the purposes of this model, housing units reported to have more than 5 ft2
       of damaged interior lead paint were classified as "bad condition" homes, as discussed
       further below.

       Lead  in  Soil.  In  the  HUD survey,  residential soil readings were taken  near the
       entrance  to  the home,  at the drip  line,  and  at  a remote  location.   Soil lead
       measurements were reported in parts per million (ppm).  To  be most representative of
       the  overall levels to which children  are  exposed,  the  arithmetic  average of the
       individual soil lead levels measurements was used to characterize each home.

       The definition of lead-contaminated soil under Section 401 of TSCA Tide IV refers
       specifically to "bare soil on residential real property that contains lead at or in excess of
       the levels determined to be hazardous" by EPA under the section 403 regulations.

       It has been noted that exposure of children to lead from soil is enhanced when they play
       on nongrassy surfaces rather than on  grass-covered areas (Madhavan et  al.,  1989;
       Lewis and Clark County Health Department et al., 1986). It has been suggested that
       contact with bare soil areas may  result in increased ingestion  of soil particles  by
       children.  Also, bare  soils may contribute more to household dust than covered soils.
       While the enhancement of lead exposure from bare soils is often noted in the technical


Abt Associates, Inc.                           3-4                       Draft, January 10.1994

-------
       literature, no studies were found that specifically addressed a quantitative difference in
       children's blood lead levels as a function of the degree of soil cover.   Most studies
       concerning the relationships between soil lead and blood lead levels do not note the
       condition of the soil with respect to grass or other form of cover.

       In the risk analysis and benefit-cost modeling that has been performed for this impact
       assessment, it has not been possible to specifically isolate and focus on lead hazards
       associated  with bare  residential soils separately from other residential  soils that  are
       partially or completely covered with grass or some other form of ground cover.

       One major impediment is that the data in the HUD survey (which provides the basis for
       the national estimates of the distribution of lead levels in residential soils used in  the
       modeling performed here)  does not include any indication as  to the condition of  the
       soils in the sample homes.  Consequently, we cannot stratify the HUD-measured levels
       of lead in the soils of the US privately-owned housing stock in terms of the condition of
       the soil as bare or covered.  No information from other sources concerning the national
       incidence of lead  levels as a  function bare or covered soil in  residential  settings is
       known to be available.  Therefore, we  are unable to estimate  either the number of
       homes that have bare soil,  or  the distribution of lead  levels in bare soils and covered
       soils.

       A second impediment is that  in the IEUBK model there is no differentiation made
       between  bare and  covered  soil in estimating intakes.  That is, lead intake  via soil is
       addressed in the IEUBK model in terms of a daily ingestion of soil.   (This is assumed
       to be 45%  of the  combined daily soil  and dust intake which ranges from  85 to  135
       mg/day depending upon age.)  The model  does  not  suggest different default values
       either for the soil fraction value or for  the total ingestion amount of soil  and dust as a
       function of prevailing  soil conditions. However, it seems reasonable  to assume that for
       a given lead concentration in soil,  lead intake  (and therefore blood lead  levels) would
       be greater for children regularly exposed to bare soils than for children exposed to soils
       that have some form of cover.  Though  not stated explicitly, it appears that the assumed
       intake values in the IEUBK model reflect an averaging of a range of intakes that may
       include contact with both bare and covered soils.

       In terms  of the  aggregate, baseline risk assessment, the inability to specifically address
       bare and covered soils may result in an "averaging out"  of the overall health damages
       by overestimating damages  for children exposed to a given lead level in  covered soils
       while underestimating damages for other children exposed to similar lead  levels in bare
       soils.  The potential  effects of this averaging out on the benefit and benefit-cost
       implications of setting a soil hazard level is discussed further in Chapters 5 and 7.
       Lead in Dust.  In the HUD survey,  floor dust lead concentrations (in ppm) were
       obtained for a wet room, dry room, and at the entry way.  An arithmetic mean of these
       measurements  was used to characterize the floor dust concentration for each  HUD


Abt Associates. Inc.                            3-5                         Draft. January 10,1994

-------
       home.  Dust lead measurements were also taken for window wells and window sills,
       but were not used in the averaging. Dust loading measurements, repotted in units of
       ug/ft2-  were also taken in the HUD study.  However, the model for predicting blood
       lead levels from exposure to dust (as described in the next section) requires dust
       concentrations, and cannot use dust loading values directly.
       For the purposes of the risk assessment model, each of the 284 HUD sample homes
 represents a group or category of homes.  The lead paint, soil,  and dust characteristics for
 every home in each of these groups is given by the measured values in the corresponding HUD
 sample home.

       The number of homes in each category is given by the weighting factor applied to the
 HUD  sample  which,  as   described  previously,  accounts  for  several  sampling  strata
 characteristics.  The sum of the HUD weights is approximately 77  million homes, which is the
 estimated current size of the privately-owned housing stock built prior to 1980. As described
 in Section 3.1.4, below, it is estimated that the total privately-owned housing stock in  1994
 (the year that is  used as the starting point for the risk assessment  modeling) is approximately
 96 million.  This implies that approximately 19 million homes were built from 1980 through
 1994 hi addition to the 77 million built prior to 1980.  Unfortunately, there is no comparable
 survey providing useful lead paint, soil, and dust measurement data for the homes built from
 1980 to  the present.   To incorporate post-1980 homes into the model,  the two assumptions
 were used.

       First, it was assumed that these homes will be free of both ulterior and exterior lead-
 based paint.  Second, it was assumed that soil  and dust lead levels in post-1980 homes will
 follow a  pattern similar to soil and dust lead levels in pre-1980 sample homes that are also free
 of lead paint.  Accordingly, the weights of the subset of pre-1980 homes in the HUD survey
 that were found to be free of both interior and exterior lead-based  paint were adjusted upward
 (proportionately) to account for the additional post-1980 homes such that the sum of all of the
 weights totaled 96 million.

       Exhibits 3-1, 3-2, and 3-3  summarize the resulting distribution of 1994 homes by paint,
 soil and dust lead levels, respectively.  These distributions reflect the data obtained for the 284
 HUD homes and the adjusted HUD weighting factors to extrapolate from those 284 samples to
 the 96  million occupied, privately-owned homes estimated for 1994.

       The data shown in Exhibit 3-1 indicate the pervasiveness of lead paint in homes despite
 the ban on its use in 1979.  Over 40% of homes, some 40 million, are still expected to have
 interior lead paint present in  1994.  While the majority of these have maximum interior XRF
 values  in the low end of the range (1 to 6 mg/cm2), there is still a substantial number of homes
 with lead paint present at very high XRF levels.  For example,  there are about  3.8 million
 homes  estimated to have lead based-paint present with a maximum interior XRF value at or
 above 10 mg/cm2.
Abt Associates, hie.                           3-6                        Draft, January 10,1994

-------
       The distribution of soil lead levels shown in Exhibit 3-2 indicates that just over half of
 all homes have average soil lead levels below 100 ppm.  About 13% of homes have soil lead
 levels at or above 500 ppm, and only 1.6% are estimated to have lead levels above 3,000 ppm.
 The maximum average value observed from the HUD survey was 8,800 ppm, affecting just
 over 200,000 homes.

       Relative to soil lead levels, there is a much higher frequency of dust levels above 100
 ppm (over 96%) as well as a higher incidence in the middle range of values, with some 36%
 exceeding 500 and about 15% exceeding 1,000 ppm. The maximum dust lead concentration
 found was 5,900 ppm.
                              Exhibit 3-1
            Summary of Distribution of Maximum Interior
                     XRF Values for 1994 Homes
Maximum Interior
XRF Measurement
22
20
13
12
11
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
Estimated Number and
Percent of 1994 Homes
174,136
1,308,115
116,914
233,828
334,584
1,596,469
1,453,400
679,926
717,116
1,735,126
646,947
634,211
2,881,551
4,902,934
21,242,577
57,675,167
0.18%
1.36%
0.12%
0.24%
0.35%
1.66%
1.51%
0.71%
0.74%
1.80%
0.67%
0.66%
2.99%
5.09%
22.05%
59.87%
Cumulative Number and
Percent of 1994 Homes
174,136
1,482,250
1,599,164
1,832,992
2,167,576
3,764,045
5,217,445
5,897,371
6,614,486
8,349,612
8,996,559
9,630,771
12,512,322
17,415,256
38,657,833
96,333,000
0.18%
1.54%
1.66%
1.90%
2.25%
3.90%
5.41%
6.12%
6.86%
8.66%
9.34%
9.99%
12.99%
18.08%
40.13%
100.00%
Abt Associates. Inc.
3-7
                                                                Draft, January 10,1994

-------
                             Exhibit 3-2
                Summary of Distribution of Average
                Soil Concentrations for 1994 Homes
Average Soil
Concentration (ppm)
8800
5800
3100
3000
2300
2200
1700
1500
1400
1300
1200
1100
1000
800
700
600
500
400
300
200
100
0
Estimated Number
of 1994 He
217.940
120,342
811,603
420,357
1,376,717
300,785
108,201
193,020
116,914
811,602
116,644
127,818
2,516,509
885,948
373,906
941,777
2,960,312
1,594,968
3,887,101
6,292,020
22,015,661
50,142,856
and Percent
>mes
0.23%
0.12%
0.84%
0.44%
1.43%
0.31%
0.11%
0.20%
0.12%
0.84%
0.12%
0.13%
2.61%
0.92%
0.39%
0.98%
3.07%
1.66%
4.04%
6.53%
22.85%
52.05%
Cumulative Number and
Percent of 1994 Homes
217,940
338,282
1,149,884
1,570,241
2,946,959
3,247,744
3,355,945
3,548,965
3,665,879
4,477,480
4,594,124
4,721,942
7,238,451
8,124,399
8,498,305
9,440,082
12,400,393
13,995,361
17,882,463
24,174,483
46,190,144
96,333,000
0.23%
0.35%
1.19%
1.63%
3.06%
3.37%
3.48%
3.68%
3.81%
4.65%
4.77%
4.90%
7.51%
8.43%
8.82%
9.80%
12.87%
14.53%
18.56%
25.09%
47.95%
100.00%
Abt Associates, Inc.
3-8
Draft, January 10.1994

-------
                            Exhibit 3-3
             Summary of Distribution of Average Floor
                Dust Concentrations for 1994 Homes
Average Dust
Concentration (ppm)
5900
5800
5300
4400
3600
3300
3200
2700
2500
2400
2100
1800
1700
1600
1500
1400
1300
1200
1100
1000
900
800
700
600
500
400
300
200
100
0
Estimated Number and
Percent of 1994 Homes
1,197,765
120,342
532,215
369,692
127,818
859,142
256,992
748,083
233,557
116,644
393,074
100,535
925,289
295,510
402,265
1,042,945
787,851
2,819,209
474,932
2,141,279
1,041,672
3,294,547
2,043,610
7,006,259
7,654,178
6,940,566
12,572,751
18,270,537
20,140,532
3,423,212
1.24%
0.12%
0.55%
0.38%
0.13%
0.89%
0.27%
0.78%
0.24%
0.12%
0.41%
0.10%
0.96%
0.31%
0.42%
1.08%
0.82%
2.93%
0.49%
2.22%
1.08%
3.42%
2.12%
7.27%
7.95%
7.20%
13.05%
18.97%
20.91 %
3.55%
Cumulative Number and
Percent of 1994 Homes
1,197,765
1,318,106
1,850,321
2,220,013
2,347,831
3,206,972
3,463,964
4,212,047
4,445,604
4,562,248
4,955,322
5,055,858
5,981,147
6,276,657
6,678,921
7,721,866
8,509,717
11,328,925
11,803,858
13,945,137
14,986,809
18,281,356
20,324,966
27,331,225
34,985,402
41,925,968
54,498,719
72,769,257
92,909,788
96,333,000
1.24%
1.37%
1.92%
2.30%
2.44%
3.33%
3.60%
4.37%
4.61%
4.74%
5.14%
5.25%
6.21%
6.52%
6.93%
8.02%
8.83%
11.76%
12.25%
14.48%
15.56%
18.98%
21.10%
28.37%
36.32%
43.52%
56.57%
75.54%
96.45%
100.00%
Abt Associates, Inc.
3-9
                                                           Draft, January 10,1994

-------
        To cany out the risk assessment modeling, some additional stratification of the 284
 categories of homes was also performed to reflect characteristics that affect exposure from
 interior lead paint in these homes.  Of the 284 HUD samples, 141 were found to have some
 lead paint present (i.e., maximum interior XRF values of 0.7 mg/cm2 or more).  Each of the
 141 groups of homes represented by these samples were divided into eight subgroups.  Note
 that the lead paint, soil and dust levels in each of these subgroups remain  the same as in the
 original group  from which each is derived.   The eight  subgroups were created using the
 following three characteristics:

    •   Based on data  presented in  the HUD  report  two  subcategories were created to
        differentiate between homes having  interior lead paint on windows (40%) and those
        that do not (60%).

    •   Using HUD data, homes with lead paint were differentiated between those having lead
        paint in bad condition  (24%) and good condition  (76%).  The criteria used for bad
        condition paint was that provided by HUD in its report as homes having more than 5
        ft2 of damaged, painted surface area.

    •   Lastly, 25% of all homes were identified as ones in which a child would exhibit pica,
        while children in the remaining 75% of homes would not have pica.  (This and other
        pica assumptions are discussed in Section 3.1.2.)

        These percentages were applied  to the weights for each HUD home having interior
paint to obtain  new weights for  each of the eight  subgroups.1   For example, if one of the
original 141 HUD samples with lead paint had a weight of 10,000 (i.e., it represents 10,000 of
the 96 million  homes  in  1994),  the eight  subgroups created from it would be weighted as
follows:
1      An alternative approach was considered for incorporating the windows and paint condition characteristics
into the modeling.  This was to simply consider these characteristics in an "all or none* manner for the homes
represented by each of the 284 HUD samples. For example, the national estimate of homes with paint in bad
condition could have been taken as the sum of the weights for each of the 284 HUD sample homes found to have
paint in bad condition. This would have implied that only those homes with those particular combinations of lead
paint, soil and dust levels have  lead paint in bad condition, while homes with all other combinations of levels
have interior paint in good condition. Similarly, homes with lead paint on windows would have been restricted in
the model to only those homes  with the particular paint, soil and dust lead combinations in the representative
HUD sample homes where lead paint on interior windows was observed.  Given the relatively small size of the
HUD sample homes, it was judged that this "all or none" approach would be less representative of the prevalence
of these conditions across all combinations of lead  levels in  paint, soil  and dust hi homes.  Therefore, the
approach used here was to apply the frequency observed (weighted by  the HUD sample weights) for these
characteristics across all homes with interior lead paint.


Abt Associates, Inc.                             3-10                          Draft, January 10,1994

-------
               Subgroup Characterisics          Weight            Derivation
        Lead paint on windows, good condition, no pica:   2,280    (= 0.4 * 0.76 * 0.75 * 10,000)
        Lead paint on windows, bad condition, no pica:      720    (= 0.4 * 0.24 * 0.75 * 10,000)
        Lead paint on windows, good condition, pica:        760    (= 0.4 * 0.76 * 0.25 * 10,000)
        Lead paint on windows, bad condition, pica:         240    (= 0.4 * 0.24 * 0.25 * 10,000)
        No lead paint on windows, good condition, no pica: 3,420    (= 0.6 * 0.76 * 0.75 * 10,000)
        No lead paint on windows, bad condition, no pica:  1,080    (= 0.6 * 0.24 * 0.75 * 10,000)
        No lead paint on windows, good condition, pica:   1,140    (= 0.6 * 0.76 * 0.25 * 10,000)
        No lead paint on windows, bad condition, pica:	360    (= 0.6 * 0.24 * 0.25 * 10.000)
       The presence or absence of lead paint on windows was used primarily in the benefits
 analysis to differentiate between homes needing full paint abatement (those without lead on
 windows) and those that could be abated by replacing the windows only.

       The homes having the combination of both lead paint in bad condition and pica children
 are particularly important for the risk analysis.  For these children, the model used to predict
 blood lead levels (described in Section 3.1.2) included special input assumptions for paint chip
 ingestion, as well as for exposure through dust and soil ingestion.
       The 143 groups of homes without interior lead paint were not further stratified in the
 model. As a result of these assumptions, the US privately-owned housing stock was ultimately
 stratified into a total of 1,271 subgroups.  Of the original 284 categories based on the HUD
 samples,  141 had interior lead paint, which were therefore stratified into 1,128 subgroups (8 x
 141).  Adding to these the 143 that did not have interior paint results in the total of 1,271.

       Having the housing stock fully stratified and properly weighted to account for the 96
 million homes in 1994, the model then applied the estimated probability of a child  being bom
 into any home of 0.03994 for 1994 to determine the number of homes in each strata expected
 to have a child in the first model year (see Section 3.1.4 for additional discussion of birth
 rates).  Blood lead distributions, and  the  incidence of adverse  health  effects,  were  then
 computed for the children born into each of the 1,271 categories of homes.
3.1.2  Determining Blood Lead Distributions

       For each of the 1,271 categories of homes created in the model, an estimate was made
of the geometric mean blood lead for the children born into them, all of whom are assumed to
live in those homes from birth through age seven.  The geometric mean blood lead estimates
were  obtained using EPA's Integrated  Exposure,  Uptake and Biokinetic Model  for lead,
hereafter referred to as the IEUBK model.

       The  IEUBK model has been developed by  EPA to use as a  tool for estimating the
geometric mean blood lead levels in populations of children exposed to various levels of lead
in environmental media.  The ffiUBK model has been under development for several years,
and has been available in several interim versions. The version  of the IEUBK model used for
this analysis became available in July 1993, and is currently undergoing validation studies.
Abt Associates. Inc.                            3-11                         Drafti January J0f 1994

-------
        The IEUBK model is designed to use data on lead concentrations in air, water, soil,
 household dust, diet, and paint chips to estimate the geometric mean (GM) blood leads for a
 population of children exposed to those  specified environmental concentrations.  To account
 for individual variability within that population of children exposed to similar environmental
 levels, it is assumed that the overall distribution of blood lead levels for that population is
 lognormal,  with an assumption made for the geometric standard deviation (GSD) of that
 distribution, as discussed further below.

        Exhibit 3-4 summarizes the IEUBK input assumptions used for this analysis.  Shown
 there are assumptions regarding levels of lead in each medium, daily intake of those media,
 and absorption of lead from each source.  The levels of lead in air and water, and the dietary
 intake values are kept constant for all children, using the values shown in the Exhibit 3-4. The
 input values for soil and dust are those in each housing group obtained from the HUD data as
 described above. The intake of lead for the subgroup of children assumed to be ingesting lead
 paint chips was estimated as follows.

        An estimate was provided by Elias (1993) that children ingesting paint chips ingest an
 average of 2.5 chips per week, each 1 cm2.  It was also assumed that these chips  are  0.1 mm
 thick, resulting in an overall size of 0.01 cm3. It was also assumed that the density of a lead
 paint chip is 2 g/cm3, a typical value for solid materials.

        A draft IEUBK guidance manual  (EPA,  1991) provided a relationship for estimating
 the lead concentration in a paint chip from the XRF measurement, which  as noted previously
 has the units of mg/cm2.  This relationship is:

                                10'100°M8pb P« XRF (mg/cm2)                   Equation 3. 1
       Therefore, a paint chip from a lead-painted surface having an XRF measurement of 10
would be estimated to have 100,000 ng of lead (or, 0. 1 g of lead) per gram of paint chip.

       Combining the above assumptions provides an estimate of the daily intake of lead from
paint chip ingestion as a function of the XRF value:
                                                                ?days
                                                                          Equation 3.2
                                   sipb per XRF
                                      day
       Therefore, a child ingesting paint chips in a home where the interior XRF value is 10
mg/cm2 is assumed to have an intake of 700 ug/day from this source.
Abl Associates. Inc.                            3-12                        Draft. January 10.1994

-------
                                          Exhibit 3-4
                 Summary of Parameter Values Used in IEUBK Model
 Air Parameters:
                      All air parameters use default values
Vary air concentration by year?
Outdoor air lead concentration (ug/m3):
Indoor air concentration (% of outdoor value):
                                                               No
                                                              0.10
                                                              30%
Diet Intake Parameters:
Age:
Diet Intake
(ug/day):
Diet parameters were reduced to 50% of default values.
0-1
2.75
1-2
2.89
2-3
3.25
3-4
3.12
4-5
3.01
5-6
3.17
6-7
3.5

Water Intake Parameters
Lead concentratio
Age:
Drinking water
consumption (L/day):
: All water parameters use default values
D in water: 4 ug/L
0-1
0.02
1-2
0.05
2-3
0.52
3-4
0.53
4-5
0.55
5-6
0.58
6-7
0.59

Soil and Dust Intake Pan
Soil/dust ingestioi
Age:
Total soil + dust
intake (g/day):
uneters: Soil and dust levels are input. All other parameters use default values.
i weighting factor: 45% soil : 55% dust
0-1
0.085
1-2
0.135
2-3
0.135
3-4
0.135
4-5
0.1
5-6
0.09
6-7
0.085

Absorption method values: (* Indicates change from default)



Soil
Dust
Water
Diet
Alternate
Total
Absorption
(percent)
0.3
0.3
0.5
0.5
0.1
Fraction of
Total Assumed
Passive Absorption
0.05 *
0.05 *
0.05 *
0.05 *
0.05 *
Abt Associates, Inc.
                                  3-13
                                                                       Draft, January 10,1994

-------
       As indicated in the previous section, homes with lead paint were stratified to isolate the
 subset having children ingesting lead paint chips.  It was estimated from the HUD data on
 paint condition that 24% of homes with interior lead paint have non-intact paint. It was also
 assumed that 25 % of children exhibit pica. This estimate was based on Baltrop (1966) as cited
 in HUD (1991) that the frequency of pica among children in inner cities is 20-30%. A lower
 estimate of pica  incidence has been provided by Mahaffey (1993) based on an analysis of
 NHANES n data indicating that the incidence of pica among children 0.5-3 years old is 11 %.
 This lower estimate became available late in the modeling process.  Incorporating it will, of
 course, reduce the computed effect of paint chip ingestion on blood lead levels.  Since there is
 a concern that this may already be underestimated in the model, as discussed in Section 3.1.5
 below,  it was decided  not to include  this  lower pica frequency estimate at this  stage.
 However, it may be included in a subsequent sensitivity analysis.

       The  combined  conditions  of non-intact  paint and pica children therefore implies an
 overall estimate that 6%  (i.e., 25% of 24%) of  children in homes with interior lead paint will
 ingest lead paint chips.

       It is important to note that for children in the remaining 94%  of homes, the blood  lead
 geometric means estimated from the ffiUBK model are not affected either by lead paint XRF
 value or by the condition of the paint in  those children's homes. That is, pica and non-pica
 children bom into homes having paint in good condition have no difference in their calculated
 blood lead levels,  all other exposure conditions being equal.  Similarly, non-pica children in
 homes with  lead paint in bad condition have the same calculated blood lead as those with  lead
 paint in good condition, all other exposure conditions being the same.  Exhibit 3-5 shows the
 predicted  blood lead levels from the EEUBK model for these various  combinations of pica and
 condition  for a given set of paint, soil and dust lead levels.
                                     Exhibit 3-5

        Comparison of Predicted Blood Lead Levels for Pica/Non-Pica Children
                 in Homes with Lead Paint in Bad or Good Condition

Lead Paint in Bad Condition
Lead Paint in Good Condition
Pica Children
13.89 ug/dl
6.93 ug/dl
Non-pica Children
6.93 ug/dl
6.93 ug/dl
Assumed exposure conditions: Interior XRF = 5 rag/cm2
Soil = 500 ppm
Dust = 500 ppm
       Exhibit 3-6 provides a summary of predicted geometric mean blood leads for soil and
dust lead concentration combinations ranging between  100 and  1,000 ppm each.  These
estimates,  which exclude  any contribution  from  paint chip  ingestion,  indicate that the
geometric means increase by about 0.5 ug/dl (ranging from about 0.35 to 0.70 ug/dl) for each


Abt Associates, hie.                            3-14                        Draft, January 10,1994

-------
 increase of 100 ppm in either soil or dust.  For example, at a soil level of 500 ppm and dust
 level of 100 ppm, the estimated geometric mean is 4.55 ug/dl.   At this same soil level, with
 dust increased to 200 ppm, the geometric mean blood lead increases to 5.18 ug/dl, a change of
 0.63  ug/dl.  The magnitude of the blood lead changes per 100 ppm  of either soil or dust
 becomes lower as the soil and/or dust level becomes higher.

       Exhibit 3-7 shows the impact of paint chip ingestion on predicted geometric means.
 For a given soil and dust concentration, the geometric mean of children ingesting paint chips is
 estimated to generally increase about 1 to 2 ug/dl per unit change in the XRF measurement,
 with the amount of increase less at high soil/dust/XRF combinations than at lower values.
Abt Associates, Inc.                            3-15                        Draft, January 10,1994

-------
                                               Exhibit 3-6
                   Estimated Blood Lead Geometric Means (ug/dl) for Various Soil-Dust
                              Combinations (excluding paint chip ingestion)
SQL
Dust Cone, (pom)
100
200
300
400
500
600
700
800
900
1000
100
2.33
3.04
3.72
4.37
5.01
5.62
6.21
6.78
7.33
7.87
200
2.91
3.60
4.26
4.89
5.51
6.10
6.68
7.23
7.77
8.29
300
3.47
4.14
4.78
5.40
6.00
6.58
7.13
7.67
8.20
8.71
400
4.02
4.67
5.29
5.89
6.47
7.03
7.58
8.10
8.61
9.11
Concentration (D
500 | 600
4.55
5.18
5.78
6.37
6.93
7.48
8.01
8.52
9.02
9.50
5.06
5.67
6.26
6.83
7.38
7.91
8.43
8.93
9.42
9.89
pm)
700
5.56
6.16
6.73
7.28
7.82
8.34
8.84
9.33
9.80
10.26
800
6.05
6.63
7.18
7.72
8.25
8.75
9.24
9.72
10.18
10.63
900
6.52
7.08
7.63
8.15
8.66
9.15
9.63
10.10
10.55
10.98
1000
6.98
7.53
8.06
8.57
9.06
9.55
10.01
10.47
10.91
11.33
Abt Associates, Inc.
3-16
                                                                                          Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                        Exhibit 3-7
              Estimated Geometric Means (ug/dl) for Children Ingesting
                   Paint Chips with Indicated XRF/Soil/Dust Levels
Soil (ppm): 100
Dust (ppm): 100
XRF: 0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
500
500

2.33
4.47
6.38
8.09
9.64
11.06
12.35
13.54
14.64
15.65
16.60
6.93
8.60
10.10
11.48
12.73
13.89
14.96
15.96
16.89
17.75
18.56
1000
1000

11.33
12.60
13.77
14.85
15.86
16.79
17.66
18.48
19.28
19.97
20.65
       The EBUBK model provides age-specific estimates of the geometric mean blood lead
for given exposure conditions  at ages ranging from birth through seven years.   For this
analysis, the blood lead geometric mean predicted  for age three was  selected to use for
estimating health damages.  This age was selected because blood lead levels tend to peak at
this age. It is also consistent with assumptions that cognitive effects are expected to occur only
after having elevated blood lead levels for a period of 3 to 4 years.
                           \
       As noted previously, the ffiUBK model produces an estimate of the geometric  mean for
an assumed lognormal distribution of blood lead levels for the population of children exposed
to similar environmental levels  of lead.   In this risk  analysis, geometric mean estimates are
made for 1,271  separate populations of  children based on the stratification  of homes  as
described in Section 3.1.1.

       The variability  of blood lead  levels within in each of these 1,271 populations is
estimated by using a standard assumption  that the geometric standard deviation (GSD) is 1.6,
regardless of the predicted geometric mean or the specific characteristics of the house where
those children are born. The assumption that the GSD is 1.6 for all subpopulations,  provided
by Schwartz  (1993a), is the best preliminary estimate of the overall population blood lead
distribution GSD obtained from the recent NHANES  m study.  As discussed further below,
this assumption that the overall population variance also applies uniformly to each subgroup
Abt Associates. Inc.
3-17
                                                                     Draft. January 10.1994

-------
 within that population results in an inconsistent outcome. That is, by assuming that the GSD is
 1.6 for each of the 1,271 subgroups, and then aggregating those 1,271 blood lead distributions
 to arrive at an overall population blood lead distribution,  the resulting GSD for this overall
 population distribution is necessarily larger than the 1.6 value used for each subgroup.  This
 effect will be discussed more fully in Section 3.1.5.
 3.1.3 Estimated Incidence of Adverse Health Effects

       The estimates of the incidence of adverse health effects resulting from exposure to lead
 in residential paint,  soil  and dust were derived primarily from the blood lead distributions
 obtained for each of the  1,271 categories of homes.  The methodology used to obtain these
 estimates is essentially identical to the  methodology that has been  used previously  for
 estimating the baseline health  effects and benefits for regulating lead levels in gasoline and
 drinking water.

       There are several  categories of adverse health effects that have  been associated with
 environmental exposure to lead. These include:

       Adults:

              Hypertension
              Non-fatal heart attack and non-fatal stroke
              Premature death from all causes
              Possible cancer
              Reproductive effects (women only)

       Infants and Children:

              Neonatal morality
              Cognitive effects, including reduced intelligence
              Interference with growth
              Interference with nervous system development
              Metabolic effects, impaired heme synthesis, anemia
              Possible cancer
       In this analysis, only effects on children have been considered.  Inadequate data are
available to fully quantify the relationships between levels of lead in residential paint, soil and
dust and adult blood lead levels.
Abt Associates, Inc.                            3-18                        Draft, January 10.1994

-------
       The adverse health effects included for children in this risk analysis are the effects on
 intelligence and neonatal mortality.  Specifically, the effects on intelligence included  in the
 analysis are:

       •   IQ point decrements

       •   Incidence of IQ < 70

       •   Low level cognitive damage, estimated from the incidence of blood lead levels >
           25 ug/dl.

       The incidence of each of these adverse effects was estimated separately for the annual
 cohort of children in each of the 1,271 housing groups, with the total for all children in that
 year's cohort obtained by summing across all subgroups.  Again, the blood lead distribution
 for each of these 1,271 subgroups were defined by the GMs obtained from the ffiUBK model
 and the assumed GSD of 1.6.

       As discussed further below, the estimates of the incidence of neonatal mortality do not
 directly involve the use of the blood lead distributions obtained from the EEUBK model.

       IP Point Decrements.  The estimate of IQ  point losses was obtained using a dose-
 response relationship  of 0.25 points lost per ug/dl of blood lead, as provided by Schwartz
 (1993b).  To obtain the total number  of IQ points lost in a population of children, the 0.25
 points lost per ug/dl change in blood lead is multiplied by the average blood lead level for that
 population.   Note that the value obtained from the IEUBK model is the  geometric mean for
 that distribution, not the arithmetic mean.  To adjust for this,  the relationship between  the
 expected value and the geometric mean of a lognormal distribution was used:


                           E(X) = exPrin(GM)+(ln(G2SD))21               Equation 3.3


 where E(X) is the expected value (mean) of the distribution, GM is the geometric mean, and
 GSD is the geometric standard deviation. Taking the log of both sides gives:


                            ln(E(X)) = ln(GM) + (ln(G2SD))2                 Equation 3.4


 Rearranging and exponentiating gives the ratio between the mean and the GM of:

                                in(E(X)) - in(GM) = ('n(G^D))2                     Equation 3.5


                                           (In(GSD))2
.  [
T
                                   GM         2                         Equation 3.6
Ma Associates, Inc.                            3-19                        Draft, January 10,1994

-------
E(X)_    r(ln(GSD))21
 GM '"T.     2J
                                                                        Equations.?
       For a GSD of 1.6, the resulting ratio between E(X) and GM is 1.117:

                          E(X)  _J(ln(1.6))21
                          	:cxpf     " •• I
                                 1   2   J
                                                                        Equation 3.8
  Therefore, the total lost IQ points for each group was estimated as:

                               GM«1.117*0.25*(Pop)k                   Equation 3.9

 where (Pop)k is the number of children in the kth group of homes.  Thus if a group of homes
 has 10,000 children and an estimated GM from the IEUBK model of 4 ug/dl, the estimated IQ
 points lost among these children due to lead is 1 1 , 170.

       Incidence of IP < 70.  The estimated incidence of IQ values below 70 was derived
 using the blood lead distributions for each housing strata in a manner similar to that above. In
 this case, however, the dose-response function is not constant across all blood lead values as in
 the case of IQ point losses.   Rather,  a  piece wise  linear  function is used to relate the
 probability of IQ <70 to blood lead as shown in Exhibit 3-8.

       Using the data shown  in Exhibit 3-8,  standardized estimates are first made  of the
 expected incidence of IQ  < 70 per unit population for blood lead distributions having GMs
 ranging from 0.5 up to SO ug/dl  (in 0.5 ug/dl increments), each with  a constant GSD of 1.6.
 For a given housing group with a particular GM predicted from the IEUBK, the incidence of
 IQ <  70 is calculated simply as the unit  value of IQ  <70 obtained from  the standardized
 estimates for a distribution with that GM, multiplied by the number of children associated with
 that housing group.
Abt Associates, Inc.                           3-20                        Draft. January 10.1994

-------
                               Exhibit 3.8
          Elements of Piecewise Linear Function for Estimating
     Probability of IQ < 70 as a Function of Blood Lead (PbB) Range
PbB Range (ug/dl)
0-5.0
5.1-7.5
7.6 - 10.0
10.1 - 12.5
12.6 - 15.0
15.1 - 17.5
17.6 - 22.5
22.6 - 25.0
> 25.0
Slope
2.04 x 10-4
4.88 x lO"4
1.068 x 10-3
1.044 x 10'3
9.76 x lO"4
1.26x10-3
1.328x10-3
1.532 x 10-3
1.464x10-3
Intercept
3.60 x 10-3
2.18x10-3
-2.17x10-3
-1.93 x 10-3
-L08 x 10-3
-5.34 x ID'3
-6.53 x 10-3
-1.112xlO-2
-9.42 x ID'3
Abt Associates, hie.
                                    3-21
Draft, January 10.1994

-------
        Blood Lead Levels  > 25 ug/dl.  The estimate of children having blood lead levels
 above 25 ug/dl, which is used as a surrogate indicator of the need for compensatory education
 due to low-level cognitive damage, is derived directly from the blood lead distributions for
 each strata using the normal distribution function with the estimated geometric mean obtained
 from the DEUBK model and the assumed geometric standard deviation of 1.6.  The probability
 of exceeding 25 ug/dl obtained from the normal distribution function for a given subgroup of
 homes is then applied to the total number of children in that subgroup.

       Neonatal Mortality. The estimation of the incidence of neonatal mortality was arrived
 at differently from the cognitive damages estimates described above.  The neonatal mortality
 estimate is based on an approach provided in the CDC (1991) report.  The CDC report used
 the following assumptions, which were also adopted here:

       •   The risk of  infant mortality is  0.0001  per ug/dl of maternal blood lead.   This is
          based  on relationships between  maternal  blood  lead  and gestational age, and
          between gestational age and infant mortality as provided by Dietrich et al. (1987).

       •   The presence of lead paint in a home corresponds with a  2.13 ug/dl increase in
          maternal blood lead. This value is used in the CDC report, attributed to Bornschein
          (personal communication).

       The  calculation  of the incidence of neonatal mortality is  therefore limited to those
 homes that have interior lead paint.  No distinctions  were  made between  paint in good
 condition or bad  condition, or between XRF levels.   The birth  rate for the first year cohort
 (0.03994 births/house, see Section 3.1.4) was used to estimate the number of pregnant women
 in each housing group for that year. Therefore,  in the first model year, a housing group with
 lead paint having a weighting factor of 100,000 units would have an estimated 0.85 additional
 cases of neonatal mortality relative to a comparable size group  with homes not having lead
 paint.  This results from:

             100,000 houses • 0.03994 births/house • 2.13 ug/dl • 0.0001 additional deaths per ug/dl

                                   = 0.85 additional deaths                         Equation 3.10


 3.1.4  Extrapolation of First Model Year Results to Full Modeling Time frame

       As discussed previously, the risk assessment modeling was premised on the assumption
 that presence of lead in paint, soil and dust  in homes in the private housing stock will continue
 to affect children born into those homes over many decades.  In the preceding sections, the
 description of the modeling methodology  used  to estimate the  incidence of adverse  health
 effects resulting from lead in paint, soil and dust focused on a single year's cohort, specifically
 that of the first year model year, i.e., 1994.
Abt Associates, Inc.                            3-22                       Draft, January 10,1994

-------
        To cany out the modeling over the 50 year time frame of 1994 to 2043,  it was first
 necessary to estimate both the size of the housing stock for each model year and the number of
 new children entering into that housing stock.  Obtaining  estimates of new children for this
 time frame was relatively straightforward.  The Bureau of Census has published a document
 entitled Population Projections of the United States by Age, Sex, Race and Hispanic Origin:
 1992 to 2050 (Bureau of Census, 1992a).  The estimated number of children under 1 year of
 age was used as the estimate of new children for each year.

        Obtaining estimates of the total housing stock for each year was less straightforward
 since there was no published projection of housing levels found for the modeling  time frame
 comparable to the population projections data noted above.  Data were available from the 1992
 Statistical Abstract of the United  States  (Bureau of Census, 1992a) and the Forecast  of
 Housing Activity (NAHB, 1992) that provided estimates through the year 2000.  To estimate
 the number  of homes from 2000  through 2043, a series of analyses were performed  on
 historical and  projected data comparing  number of persons in various  age  groups per
 household from 1960 to 2000 to find the best indicator to use for the 2000 to 2043 projections.
 Of the several approaches compared (specifically, using adults per household of  ages 18+,
 21+, 25+ and 18-64), the best predictor was found to be a  ratio of 1.85 adults 21 + years old
 per household for the period 1980-2000.

       Using that ratio with the population projections through 2050 for adults  21 and over
 from the sources noted above, the estimate of the total occupied housing stock for each year
 through 2050 was obtained.  An adjustment was also made to eliminate public housing, to
 limit the analysis to  privately-owned, occupied  housing.   Exhibit  3-9  summarizes the
 projections for housing stock and children  <  1 year old for  the years  1990 through 2050.
 Also shown there is the probability of a new child being born into a home in each year, which
 is simply the number of children  <  1 year old divided by the number of total occupied homes
 for that year.

       In addition to  the  overall  change  in  the size  of the housing  stock,  the model
 incorporated  assumptions regarding the distribution of homes between those with and without
 lead paint. As noted in Section 3.1.1, it was assumed that  all  homes built between 1980 and
 1994 are free of lead paint and have lead soil and dust characteristics like those in the pre-1980
 housing stock without lead paint.   Similarly, it was assumed that all new housing added to the
 stock for the remaining 49 years of the model time frame would be added proportionately to
 the groups of homes without lead paint

       It was also assumed that existing homes  disappear from the housing stock at a rate of
 0.5% per year, based on data  derived from  the Annual  Housing Survey Components  of
 Inventory Change:  1973 to 1983 (Bureau of Census, 1991). While this factor is assumed to
 be the same for all types of homes regardless of its age  or the presence/absence of lead paint,
 the effect in  this model is to reduce the proportion of  lead paint homes relative to the total
 number of homes over the modeling period.  In 1994, it is estimated from the HUD data that
 approximately 51 million of the 96 million privately-owned occupied homes  have either
 interior or exterior lead paint, comprising 53 % of the total.
Abt Associates, Inc.                           3-23
                                                                    Draft, January 10,1994

-------
Exhibit 3-9. Estimafc
and Child
Kama
JWU



































2026



2030
2031

2033

2035
2036

2038




2043
2044
204S


2048

20SO
93*345

























121.571

123.S29







131.559



135.206
136.031

137.682

139.332
140.157

141.807




145.620
146.341
147,061


149.224

150.666

ren < 1 Year Old for 1990 - 2050
Occupied PrivttelrOwncd OuUraK 1 Y«r Pratabilfeof.
Hmm OU Chiy < i Y nu
91.177
92.991

95.219


98.562

100.790
101.904



105.905



109.755
110.717
111.680



115.931

118.124


121.413


124.484

126.243
127.122
128.001
128.881

130.639
131.518
132.397
133.190

134.774

136.359
137.152

138.736
139,529

141.009

142.385
143.073
143,761


145.826
146.514
147.202
4.008



3.912



3.817
3.793



3,890

3.904

3.957
3,984

4.038

4.093

4.149
4.177
4.204
4.232
4.260
4.287
4.315
4.327
4.338
4.350
4.361
4.373



4.419
4.431
4.458
4.485
4.513
4.540
4.567

4.621

4,676


4.748
4.771
4.793
4,816

4.861

4.906
4 928



































0.0335




0.0328


0.0328
0.0328


0.0328




0.0328
0.0328
0.0328


0.0327

0.0327 |
0 0327 11
Abt Associates, Inc.
3-24
                                                                     Draft, January 10,1994

-------
       Over the SO year period, with an annual loss rate of 0.5%, these 51  million homes
 would decrease to about 39.7 million (51  * 0.99550).   At the same time, the total occupied
 privately-owned housing stock in 2043 is estimated to be 142.4 million.  Therefore, in 2043,
 the final year of the modeling time frame, houses with either interior or exterior lead paint are
 estimated to comprise only 28% of the total.
       The modeling of these temporal  changes in the size of the housing stock,  proportion
 of lead paint housing, and birth rates could be done by "brute force,"  iterating through each
 of the 50 years of the model time frame to calculate the incidence separately in each year, and
 then sum across all years to arrive at the total.  A computational shortcut was used, however,
 taking advantage of the fact that  children  born into any one of the 1,271  housing categories
 will have the same predicted blood lead  distribution regardless of the year in which those
 children are bom.  The number of children to whom that distribution applies will vary from
 year to year reflecting changes in the size of the housing stock and the birth rate.  However,
 the blood lead distribution for children in that category of homes will remain the same.

       The computed incidence  of adverse  health  effects is a  function  of blood  lead
 distributions and the number of children in the population characterized by those distributions.
 Since the predicted blood lead distributions are constant in each category of homes over time,
 the total incidence of adverse effects to all children bom into a particular category of homes
 over time is related to that total  number of children.  Therefore, the ratio of total children
 expected to be bom into  those homes over the full modeling time frame to the  number  of
 children born in the first year can be used as a multiplier to apply to the incidence of adverse
 effects calculated for the  children bora in the  first year to obtain  the incidence  of adverse
 effects for children bom over the entire modeling time frame.

       Sections 3.1.4.1 and 3.1.4.2 discuss the derivation of these multipliers for homes with
 lead paint and homes without lead paint, respectively.  There are different multipliers for these
 two types of homes because of the difference in housing dynamics for each (i.e., the number
 of lead paint homes is  decreasing over time while the number of non-lead  paint homes  is
 increasing). Note,  however, that  among all HUD-based categories of homes with  lead paint,
 the multiplier is the same. Similarly,  there is just one multiplier for all of the HUD-based
 categories of homes without lead paint.

       The notation used for the variables in these derivations tends to be intricate, and so a
 summary of the key variables with various notations is provided in Exhibit 3-10.
Abt Associates, Inc.                            3-25                        Draft, January 10,1994

-------
                                     Exhibit 3-10
                     Summary of Key Variables Used in Derivation
                                 of Model Multipliers
B,
rT|LP
^J30
CFBHJ>
CFB|LP
pFBILP
*TSO
QTILP
H.LP
pTjNLP
'"ESO
p.FB|NLP(j)
*T50
TT*NLP(J)
*i
Probability of having a child bom into a home in Model Year
/..
Total number of children bom into lead paint homes over the
full modeling time frame.
First bom children in lead paint homes in Model Year 1 .
First born children in lead paint homes in Model Year i.
Total first bom children in lead paint homes over the full
modeling time frame.
Total number of children born into lead paint homes over the
full modeling time frame in which the first child is bom in
Model Year i..
Number of lead paint homes hi Model Year i that have not yet
had a child born into them. For /= 1 this is the number of lead
paint homes in 1994 ( = 49, 130 million).
Total number of children bom into non-lead paint homes over
the full modeling time frame.
Number of first bom children in non-lead paint homes added to
the housing stock in Model Year / .
Number of non-lead paint homes added to the housing stock in
Model Yeary that have not yet had a first child born into them
in Model Year / . For i = 1 , j = 1 this is the number of non-lead
paint homes in the housing stock in 1994 (= 47,203 million).
       Each multiplier involves two components.  The first component is to account for the
total number of "first bom" children in homes over the full modeling time frame. That is, for
1994 (the first model year) we estimate the number of children bom based on the number of
homes present and the per-home probability of a child being born. In the second year, another
portion of homes will have a first bom child based on the number of homes in the second year
that haven't yet had a child and the per-home birth probability for the second year.  Similarly,
over each of the remaining 50 years, there will be a particular number of "first bom" children.
The  first multiplier component addresses the total  of these first bom children during the SO
year period of 1994 to 2043.

       The second component of the multiplier accounts for the expected number of additional
children bom subsequently into those homes that have already had a first child born into them.
For this second component, we have estimated the expected number of additional children that
Abt Associates, Inc.
3-26
Draft. January 10.1994

-------
 would be born during additional 50 year time period beyond the birth of the first child.  That
 is, for homes having a first child born in the first model year of 1994, the second part of the
 multiplier reflects an estimate for additional children born in these homes through 2043.  For
 homes not having a first child born until the last model year of 2044, the multiplier reflects the
 expected number of additional children born in those homes through 2093.

 Multiplier for homes with lead paint

       The overall multiplier for homes with lead paint can be expressed as:

                                            C71""
                                      MU>=£5§F                        Equation 3-11

  where: C£jf is the total number of children bom into homes with lead paint, and
         CfB|LP is the number of children bom into homes with lead paint in Model Year 1
         (1994).

       As noted above, the first component of the multiplier addresses the total number of first
 born children over the 50 year modeling time frame.  The number of first births in lead paint
 homes in each model year can be computed as:

                                   CH,IP=(H*U>)(B)                     Equation 3-12


 where: Cf81"" is the number of first births in lead paint homes in year i;
       H""* is the number of lead paint homes in that category in Year i that have not yet had
       a child born into them; and
       B, is the per home probability of a birth for year i.

       The total number of first births in lead paint homes is, then, the sum of  the numbers for
 each individual year:


                                 CzT" = BH^XB,)                     Equation 3.13
                                         1=1

       From  the data presented in Exhibit 3-9, we know the  value for each B, (where / = 1
 for 1994).  We also know from the HUD data the value for H*"", which  is simply the total
 number of lead paint homes in 1994, estimated to be 49 million. (Note: This number is higher
 than the 38.7 million shown in Exhibit 3-1 as having interior XRF values greater than 0, since
 the definition of lead paint homes used here includes both those with interior and exterior lead
 paint.
Abt Associates, Inc.                            3-27
                                                                     Draft. January 10.1994

-------
       We do not know, directly, the values for H^ for Model Years 2 through SO; however,
 these values can be derived as follows.  For Model Year 2, the number of lead paint homes
 that have not yet had a child born into them is:
                                       -(H7P.B1)).0.995               Equation 3.14
 That is, the number of homes at the start of Model Year 2 not yet having a first birth is equal
 to the number at the start of in Model Year 1 not having a first birth, less the number that do
 have a child bom in Model Year 1, reduced by 0.5% to account for loss in the housing stock
 that year.

 Similarly, the number for Model Year 3 can be expressed as:

                            H?* = (H;1* -(H? .B2)).0.995               Equation 3.15

 Note that the values for Model Year 3 are expressed in terms of Model Year 2 values, which
 in turn are expressed in terms of Model Year 1 values.  Therefore, the expression for Model
 Year 3 can be written in terms of Model Year 1 values as:

                     Hi"" = (H2nj>-(H^J>.B2)).0.995
                          = (H;LP).(1-B2).0.995                        Equation 3.16
                          = (H|")*(1-B1)«0.995*(1-B2)«0.995

       Similarly, the value for each subsequent year can also be expressed in terms of the birth
 rates for each year and the (constant) value H*"".


 This can be generalized as:


                          H;u> = H;Lp.(n;(l-B,)).0.9951-1               Equation 3.17


 Substituting this for H*Lpinto Equation 3-13  gives:

                                   50
                                                                        Equation 3.18
       We can now compute the number of first bom children in the lead paint homes from
the birth rate information in Exhibit 3-9, and the number of lead paint homes.  We can also
express an interim multiplier as the ratio of all first bom children in lead paint homes over the
50 year time frame to the first bom children in lead paint homes in Model Year 1 as:
Abt Associates, Inc.                           3-28                        Draft, January 10,1994

-------
                                                                         Equation 3.19
       It is useful to note that for this multiplier, the value for H*""drops out. Therefore, the
 first birth component of the multiplier for lead paint homes is a function only of the birth rates
 over the SO year period and the assumed loss rate of 0.5% per year. From the data in Exhibit
 3-11, it can be shown that the value for Mra|U>is:


                                              19.08                       Equation 3.20


       The summation values for each model year that result in 0.7623 for the numerator are
 shown in Exhibit 3-11. The denominator value of 0.03994  is the per home birth probability
 for 1994.

       As noted above, this interim multiplier addresses only the number of total first births in
 lead paint homes.  That is, the total number of first births in lead  paint homes from 1994 to
 2043 is 19.08 times the number of first births in 1994.

       To obtain the second component of the multiplier that accounts for additional children
 expected to be bom into the homes subsequent to the first child, we begin with the 1994 birth
 rate multiplied by SO  to obtain  the  expected number of children over an ensuing SO year
 period. This value is:

                                (0.03994) (50) = 1.998                   Equation 3.21

       However, since these homes are being lost from the stock at  a rate of 0.5% per year, it
 is necessary to adjust this number downward to account for homes that will be lost before this
 additional SO years is complete.  The probability that  a home survives through  50 years with
 an annual loss rate of 0.5 % is given by:

                           (1 - 0.005)50 = (0.995)50 = 0.778              Equation 3.22
Abt Associates, Inc.                            3-29                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                  Exhibit 3-11.  Elements of Summation Component for
i
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
IS
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
B;
0
0.0399
0.0392
0.0386
0.0379
0.0372
0.0366
0.0359
0.0359
0.0358
0.0357
0.0356
0.0355
0.0355
0.0354
0.0353
0.0352
0.0352
0.0351
0.0350
0.0349
0.0348
0.0347
0.0346
0.0345
0.0344
0.0343
0.0342
0.0341
0.0339
0.0338
0.0336
0.0335
0.0333
0.0332
0.0330
0.0329
0.0328
0.0328
0.0328
0.0328
0.0328
0.0328
0.0328
0.0328
0.0328
0.0328
0.0328
0.0328
0.0328
0.0328
n-B,-)
1.0000
0.9601
0.9608
0.9614
0.9621
0.9628
0.9634
0.9641
0.9641
0.9642
0.9643
0.9644
0.9645
0.9645
0.9646
0.9647
0.9648
0.9648
0.9649
0.9650
0.9651
0.9652
0.9653
0.9654
0.9655
0.9656
0.9657
0.9658
0.9659
0.9661
0.9662
0.9664
0.9665
0.9667
0.9668
0.9670
0.9671
0.9672
0.9672
0.9672
0.9672
0.9672
0.9672
0.9672
0.9672
0.9672
0.9672
0.9672
0.9672
0.9672
0.9672

n',»-'>-i>
..
1.0000
0.9601
0.9224
0.8868
0.8532
0.8215
0.7914
0.7630
0.7356
0.7093
0.6840
0.6596
0.6362
0.6136
0.5919
0.5710
0.5508
0.5315
0.5128
0.4949
0.4776
0.4610
0.4450
0.4297
0.4148
0.4006
0.3868
0.3736
0.3609
0.3486
0.3368
0.3255
0.3146
0.3041
0.2940
0.2843
0.2750
0.2660
0.2572
0.2488
0.2407
0.2328
0.2251
0.2178
0.2106
0.2037
0.1970
0.1906
0.1843
0.1783
(0.995)*'1
__
1.0000
0.9950
0.9900
0.9851
0.9801
0.9752
0.9704
0.9655
0.9607
0.9559
0.9511
0.9464
0.9416
0.9369
0.9322
0.9276
0.9229
0.9183
0.9137
0.9092
0.9046
0.9001
0.8956
0.8911
0.8867
0.8822
0.8778
0.8734
0.8691
0.8647
0.8604
0.8561
0.8518
0.8475
0.8433
0.8391
0.8349
0.8307
0.8266
0.8224
0.8183
0.8142
0.8102
0.8061
0.8021
0.7981
0.7941
0.7901
0.7862
0.7822
50
I(fi;i1-Bj)).{Bj)-0.995M
i th Year Quantity
of SunviiBtion
_ ,
0.0399
0.0375
0.0352
0.0331
0.0311
0.0293
0.0276
0.0264
0.0253
0.0242
0.0232
0.0222
0.0212
0.0203
0.0195
0.0187
0.0179
0.0171
0.0164
0.0157
0.0150
0.0144
0.0138
0.0132
0.0127
0.0121
0.0116
0.0111
0.0106
0.0102
0.0097
0.0093
0.0089
0.0086
0.0082
0.0079
0.0075
0.0072
0.0070
0.0067
0.0065
0.0062
0.0060
0.0058
0.0055
0.0053
0.0051
0.0049
0.0047
0.0046
0.7623
Abt Associates, Inc.
3-30
                                                                     Draft. January 10,1994

-------
  Combining these, the expected number of children born into homes having had a first child is:


                                 (1.998) (0.778) = 1.55                    Equation 3.23


        Therefore, for each first born child in a home in each year, there  is an  expected
 number of 1.55 additional children over the ensuing 50 years.


        The total number of children over the full modeling time frame expressed in terms of
 the number of first born children each year is:
                            r =                       Equation 3.26
                                           1=1


 and, as can be seen from the numerators in Equations 3-19 and 3-20,
                                         H;LP. 0.7623                     Equation 3.27


 the overall multiplier for lead paint homes can be expressed as:
                           MLP = Cf   2.55. H;"*. 0.7623
                                         2.55.0.7623
                                       =   0.03994                       Equation 3.28



                                       = 48.65
       Therefore, to estimate the total incidence of adverse effects for children born in lead

paint homes, the incidence of adverse effects obtained for the first year cohort is multiplied by
48.65.
Abt Associates. Inc.                            3-31                         Draft Jmuary ]Q ]994

-------
 Multiplier for homes with no lead paint

       Obtaining the multiplier for the homes without lead paint is conceptually similar to the
 derivation for homes with lead paint, but the computation is complicated by the nature of the
 change in the size of the stock of these  homes over the SO year modeling period.  For lead
 paint homes, the stock was assumed to change with a constant loss rate over the SO year period
 of 0.5%  per year.   As a result, a  constant term could be used in the Equations (see, for
 example ???) to reflect this rate.  In the case of homes without lead paint, however, the annual
 rate of change is not constant. As shown in Exhibit 3-9, the total number of privately-owned
 homes increases each year from  1994 through 2043. It is assumed that the new homes added
 each year are free of lead paint.

       It is important to note that the number new homes added to the housing stock in a given
 year is not just the difference between the total for that year and the total for the previous year.
 Since older homes (both with and without lead paint) are disappearing at a rate of 0.5% per
 year, the number of new, no lead paint homes  each year is the sum of the difference between
 the totals for those years, plus 0.5 % of the preceding year's total stock.

       To derive the multiplier  for homes without lead paint,  it is  useful to consider  these
 homes in terms of SO separate groups.  The first group is the non-lead paint homes that are
 present in Model Year 1.   The remaining 49 groups are the new, non-lead paint homes added
 to the stock each remaining year. It is assumed that each of these SO groups has the same loss
 rate characteristic as  noted in the preceding section for  homes with lead paint. That is, it is
 assumed that they disappear from the stock with the same annual loss rate of 0.5 %.  By using
 this approach, we can develop  equations similar to those for  homes with lead  paint (i.e.,
 having the constant loss rate of 0.5% per year) to determine the total  number of first births in
 these homes from the year they are added to the stock through the end of Model Year 50. The
 first birth obtained for each of these 50 groups can then  be summed, and a multiplier obtained
 expressed as the ratio of this sum to the number of first birth children in non-lead paint homes
 in Model Year 1.

       The number of first births over the full SO years just in the non-lead paint homes that
 are present in Model Year 1 is expressed as:

                              so

                                                                       Equation 3.29
                                      so
which is similar in form to Equation 3-18.

       For the new lead paint homes added in Model Year 2,  the number of first births
through Model Year 50 is given by:
Abt Associates, Inc.                           3-32                       Draft. January 10.1994

-------
                               so
                                        jo                                 Equation 3.30
                                       1=2
       Note that here the summation begins with Model Year 2.

       Similarly, for homes that enter the stock in model year 3, the number of first births
 over the duration of model year 3 to model year 50 is:
                                                                          Equation 3.31
                                       1=3
       Again, the summation in this case begins with Model Year 3.

       The total number of first births in homes without lead paint is, then, the sum of these
 first birth calculations for each of the 50 groups of homes:
                                           so
                                   CFB/NLP _ V1 r-FB'NIJ'G)                     f   *•   t -»o
                                   iso    -2-c«o                         Equation 3.32
       Exhibit 3-12 shows the first birth values calculated for each of 50 groups of non-lead
paint homes over the 50  year time frame, as well as the sum of these, shown there to be
73,648 M children. To convert this to an interim multiplier addressing only first births, both
sides of Equation 3.32 are divided by the number of first births in non-lead paint homes in
Model Year 1:
                                          so          so

                                 -,FB/NLP
                                C         -
                       M  /NLP = cFB/NLPd) = JgFB/NLp(i)  = ^»NLp(i)>B           Equation 3.33
       Using the values shown in Exhibit 3-12 of 73,648 for the numerator and 47,203 for the
number of non-lead paint homes in Model Year 1 in the denominator, as well as the value of
0.03994 in the denominator for the per home probability of birth described previously, an
interim "first birth" multiplier is obtained as:
                                                                         E,«aaon3.34
Abt Associates, Inc.                            3-33                        Draft. January 10.1994

-------
                                    Exhibit 3-12
               Summary of New Non-Lead-Faint Homes and First Births
                    in These Homes over the 50 Year Model Period
Ywfrt
1
2
3
4
5

7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
New, No-Lead-Paint Homes in this
Model Year
47.203
1.596
1.601
1.607
1.612
1.618
1.624
1.478
1.482
1.487
1.492
1.497
1.502
1.506
1.511
1.516
1.521
1.660
1.665
1.670
1.676
1.681
1.687
1.692
1.698
1.703
1.709
1.497
1.502
1.506
1.510
1.515
1.519
1.524
1.532
1.537
1.454
1.462

.470
1.474
.478
1.482
.490
.390
1.393
1.397 1
Total No-Lead-Paint Homes with Tint Births'
Through 2043
Total "First Births' in This Year's New
35.982
1.207
1.201
1,195 	
1.189
1.182
1.176
1,060 	 	
1.053
1,046 	
1.038
1,030 	
	 1,021 	
1,011 	
1,001 	 ^___^
991

1,053 	
1,039 	
1,025 	 	
	 1,010 	
994

960
942
922
902
769
749
729
707
685
661
	 	 	 637
584
556
	 , 	 497
438
407
374
339
303
	 265
185
132
90
46

Abt Associates, Inc.
3-34
                                                                 Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
        Therefore, the total number of first births in homes with no lead paint over the SO year
 model period is computed as 39.06 times the number of first births in non-lead paint homes in
 model year 1. To obtain the overall multiplier to account for both first birth and subsequent
 births in these homes,  the additional factor of 2.55 is  applied,  as described previously for
 homes with lead paint.  Thus, the overall multiplier is:

                              MUNLP = (39 06)(2.55) = 89.60                Equation 3.35

       Therefore, to obtain the total incidence of adverse effects for children bom into homes
 without lead paint, the incidence computed for children bom into those homes  in the first
 model year is multiplied by 89.60.
 3.1.5 Discussion of Results for Baseline Risk Assessment

       The discussion of the results of the baseline risk assessment focuses on the blood lead
 distribution obtained for  the first year of the model period.  Because  most  of the other
 measures of adverse health effects (e.g., incidence of IQ point losses) are difficult to interpret
 until combined with information on  the value of those damages and the  societal benefits
 attained by avoided those damages, these latter aspects are addressed in subsequent chapters of
 this document addressing benefits and benefit-cost comparisons.

       As discussed in the preceding sections, the blood lead distribution for the first  model
 year cohort of children is  obtained by separately estimating blood lead  distribution geometric
 means for 1,271 groups of children associated with homes that are differentiated by their paint,
 soil and dust levels (plus paint condition and pica potential).  The geometric means are based
 on the value obtained from the ffiUBK  for children exposed to those conditions continually
 from birth through age 7,  with the blood lead for age three used as the representative  value.
 Along with these estimated geometric means, the blood lead distributions  for these  1,271
 groups of children are all assumed to have a geometric standard deviation of 1.6.

       Exhibit 3-13 depicts the distribution of geometric means resulting from this modeling
 process.  As shown by this histogram, the distribution of the GMs is right skewed, with most
 children expected to be in  homes where GMs are expected to be in the range of 1 to 6  ug/dl,
 with generally  decreasing  frequencies of GMs at higher values.  The maximum GM predicted
 for any housing category was 30.1 ug/dl.

       Again, these values are the  predicted geometric means for 1,271 groups of children.
 The overall population distribution  of blood lead levels was obtained by first estimating the
 number of children in each 1 ug/dl  range from 1 to 50 ug/dl (plus a total for those exceeding
 50 ug/dl) for each of these 1,271  distributions using the standard normal distribution function.
 The geometric standard deviation used in all of these computations was assumed  to  be a
 constant 1.6 for all group, as discussed before.
Abt Associates, Inc.                           3-35
                                                                    Draft, January 10,1994

-------
                                                            Exhibit 3-13
                                Distribution of Predicted Baseline Geometric Means for First Year Cohort
         25% T

      §
      |  20% -
      S
      1
      I  15% 4
      =  10% 4

          5% -
          0%
                                                                                  «—  CN  en  *• in  CD  r*.  CD
                                                      Gwmetric Mean PbB (ugfdQ
Exhibit 3-14
Distribution of Predicted Baseline Population Blood Lead Levels for First Model Year Cohort
(1994)
18.00% -
I 18.00% -
^ 14.00%
^ 12.00% -
E 10.00% •
2
iZ 8.00% -
5 6.00% -
3
g 4.00% -
4 2.00% -
000% -







1






Illlllllll...... .... 	
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 B 9 1011 1Z 13 14 IS 1617 18)92021 22 23 2425 X 27 28 29 30 31 32 3334 36 3637 38 39 40 41 42 4344 45 46 47 48 49 60
Blood lend Laval (ugMD
Abt Associates, Inc.
3-36
                                                                                                Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                  Exhibit 3-15

   Characteristics of Baseline Population Blood Lead Distribution and a
                   Distribution with GM = 5, GSD = 1.6

Mean
Geometric Mean
Geometric Standard Dev.
Median
90th Percentile
95th Percentile
% > lOug/dl
% > 15 ug/dl
% > 20 ug/dl
% > 25 ug/dl
From Modeled Baseline From a Distribution with
Distribution GM = 5.0 and GSD = 1.6
6.09 ug/dl
4.06 ug/dl
2.45 ug/dl
3.91 ug/dl
13.32 ug/dl
18.85 ug/dl
15.99%
8.03%
4.37%
2.47%
5.58 ug/dl
5.00 ug/dl
1.60 ug/dl
5.00 ug/dl
9. 13 ug/dl
10.83 ug/dl
7.01%
0.97%
0.16%
0.03%
       To arrive at the overall population blood lead distribution for the first year cohort, the
predicted number of children in each 1 ug/dl range for all 1,271 groups were added together.
Exhibit 3-14  provides a histogram  of  the overall distribution arrived at by  this  process.
Exhibit 3-15 summarizes the characteristics of this distribution.

       The mean shown in Exhibit 3-15  was obtained by assuming a mid-point value in each
of the 50 concentrations ranges (e.g., a value of 5.5 ug/dl was used for the children predicted
to fall between 5 and 6 ug/dl).  The geometric mean was obtained  in  a similar manner by
taking  the natural logs of  these values,  computing  the  mean  of  the  log  values  and
exponentiating. The geometric standard deviation was obtained from the normal formula for a
sample  standard deviation,  using the log transformed values and weighting the differences
between the mean of the logs and the log of the mid-points of each range by the number of
children in that range.

       For comparison,  values are also included  in Exhibit 3-15 for a lognormal distribution
having  the parameters of GM=5 and GSD=1.6, which has  been  suggested  by  Schwartz
(1993a) as  the current population blood lead distribution parameters for children  under 7.
Exhibit  3-16 superimposes a histogram based on the GM=5, GSD=1.6 parameters onto the
baseline population blood lead distribution histogram shown previously in Exhibit 3-10.

      The central tendency values  for the modeled baseline distribution and  the GM=5,
GSD=1.6 distribution are slightly lower than those for  the GM=5,  GSD=1.6 distribution,
reflected by the lower values  for the  geometric mean and median.  The GM=5, GSD=1.6
distribution indicates  higher values than the model  in the range of abut 5 to 11 ug/dl, after
which  point   the  model  values  exceed  the  GM=5,  GSD=1.6  distribution   values.
Abt Associates, Inc.
3-37
                                                                   Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 Cumulatively, the modeled distribution is far more right skewed than the GM=5, GSD=1.6
 distribution, however.  For example, only 7% of the population would be expected to exceed
 10 ug/dl from the GM=5, GSD=1.6 distribution, whereas the model predicts over twice that
 frequency (16%).
                                             Exhibit 3-16
                     Comparison of Baseline Blood Lead Distribution with GM=6, GSD=1.6 Distribution
  20.00%

  18.00%

 = 16.00%

§ 14.00%
u
m 12.00%

• 10.00% •

f  8.00% •
M
E  6,00% -
o
*  4.00% -

   2.00%

   0.00%
                                                            • Btjeline Distribution

                                                            D GM-5,6SD-1.6Distibution
                                          Blood Lead Level (ug/dD
       The GM=5, GSD=1.6 distribution also predicts only about 0.03% of the population
 exceeding 25 ug/dl, whereas as  the  model predicts  almost 2.5%.   Schwartz  (1993a) has
 suggested that this value is currently about 0.5% to 1 % based on a preliminary assessment of
 the NHANES m data.

       It is useful to examine the source of the population above  25 ug/dl predicted by the
 model. Exhibit 3-17 provides a summary of the distribution of the blood lead levels above 25
 ug/dl predicted by the model among different exposure conditions.  As shown there, children
 with pica in homes having lead paint in bad condition have the highest individual risk of blood
 leads exceeding 25 ug/dl, at  9.2%.  By comparison, children in homes with either interior of
 exterior  lead paint, but without ingesting paint chips have a predicted incidence of blood lead
 above 25 ug/dl of about 3 %.  Children in homes without lead paint are predicted to have blood
 leads above 25 ug/dl only 1.6% of the time.

       Notwithstanding the  higher predicted rate of high  blood leads for children ingesting
 lead paint chips,  the overall  number of such children predicted is only about 9% of the total
 having these high blood leads.  Other sources have suggested that paint chip ingestion is  a
 much larger contributor to  these  high blood leads than these results show.   For example,
 Shannon and Graef  (1992) found  that paint chip ingestion was the origin of elevated  blood
 leads for 80-90% of  toddlers  with elevated  blood leads entering the  Lead/Toxicology Program
at Boston's Children Hospital.  For infants, by contrast,  paint chip ingestion  appeared to
account for only about 20% of the cases.
Abt Associates, Inc.
                                      3-38
                                                                      Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                              Exhibit 3-17
         Blood Leads > 25 Related to Exposure Conditions
II Total Children
I Exposure Conditions in First Year # > 25 % > 25
[interior lead paint in bad condition,
|[paint chip ingestion
[interior lead paint (may also have
exterior lead paint), any condition,
no paint chip ingestion
llExterior lead paint, no interior lead
llpaint, no paint chip ingestion
|No interior or exterior lead paint, no
llpaint chip ingestion
94,271
1,476,903
406,957
1,937,141
8,688
43,971
12,416
31,548
9.22%
2.98%
3.05%
1.63%
Totals: 3,915,272 96,623 2.47%

Percent of PbB >25 related to paint chip ingestion
Odds ratio of PbB > 25 for Lead paint present : No lead paint
present
8.99%
2.02
       Also,  Schwartz and Levin (1991) found that the odds ratio of having blood leads
exceeding 30 ug/dl ranged from 5.70 to  12.81 given paint lead exposure.  The population
studied was children i n Chicago for  1976 through 1980, when leaded gasoline was still a
major contributor of elevated blood leads. One would expect, therefore, a higher odds ratio
currently than observed in those data.  However, the model results indicate an odds ratio of
only about 2.

       Except for 8,688 children predicted to have blood leads above 25 ug/dl due to paint
chip ingestion, all other cases of high blood leads in the model are occurring from ingestion of
soil and/or dust having somewhat elevated lead levels. The lead levels in these soils and dusts
for most of the approximately 88,000 non-pica children with high blood leads tend to be above
1,000 ppm.  Approximately 76,000 of these cases (86%) occur in cases when dust levels
exceed 1,000 ppm, and 32,500 (37%) occur when soil levels exceed 1,000 ppm.

       Since there is some overlap between these, a weighted average of the soil and dust lead
levels was computed, using 55% dust and 45%  soil (the assumption made for ingestion in the
ffiUBK model).  Over 81,000 children  with blood leads  above 25 ug/dl (92% of the non-pica
group) are exposed to weighted average soil/dust concentrations of 1,000 ppm or more, and
about 54,000 (61 %) are at or above weighted average soil/dust concentrations of 2,000 ppm.
Abt Associates, Inc.
3-39
                                                                   Draft, January 10,1994

-------
 3.2    MARKET FAILURE

        From an economic perspective, one necessary condition for regulatory intervention is the
 existence of an inefficiency in the allocation of resources. This inefficiency is commonly labeled
 a market  failure since  the  market is  the  mechanism assumed to  make efficient resource
 allocations possible.  The cause of a market failure can come from one or more of several
 sources.  These include poorly defined property rights (such as negative externalities, common
 property resources, and public goods); imperfect markets for trading property rights (because
 of a lack of perfect information or of contingent markets; monopoly power; distortionary taxes
 and subsidies and other inappropriate government interventions); and the divergence of private
 and social discount rates.2

        The occurrence of any of  these conditions justifies further inquiry into the need for
 government intervention to reduce inefficiencies  in the allocation of society's resources.   This
 section considers whether any of  these conditions are linked to excess exposures from  lead
 contamination in residential soil, dust, and paint.  If so, a better understanding of the nature of
 the inefficiencies involved may  facilitate the design of effective interventions.  The specific
 intervention considered here is the promulgation  of hazard levels as mandated by Section  403.

        The strongest case for the existence of a market failure can be built on the apparent lack
 of perfect  information.  The right  information is an important prerequisite to the demand for
 abatement. The homeowner making the abatement decision has to know the levels of lead in
 soil, dust,  or paint; know what risks are implied by these levels;  know the significances of these
 risks;  and know what can be accomplished through various forms of abatement.  Clearly,
 without knowing there is a lead problem, the homeowner will have too low  a  demand for
 abatement. Misinformation on the other attributes of the abatement decision can also distort the
 demand for abatement. Research into public views of risk indicate how common misperceptions
 are in  the assessment of latent  risks like those  associated with lead contamination. These
 misperceptions can be  biased upward  or downward, resulting respectively  in  excess  and
 insufficient demand for abatement.  Finally, reliable information on the relative and absolute
 effectiveness of different abatement alternatives could be a significant obstacle.

       The market itself has not provided a means  for correcting the situation.   Although
 businesses  offering testing or abatement services  should find it in their vested interest to offer
 the kinds of information cited above, this possibility has not closed the information gaps for the
 public. One impediment may be public uncertainty about the reliability of the information that
 such businesses would provide. Their information may be unreliable because they are not fully
 competent  to assess the lead contamination and what needs to be done, because the businesses
 are subject to moral hazard (which occurs, for example, when  a firm tells a homeowner  that
 there is a lead problem that warrants a certain abatement it can perform when the abatement is
 not necessary or suitable),  or both.  Since many homeowners may lack easy access to
 independent sources of information to motivate their abatement decisions,  doing nothing may be
 the likely response.
             This taxonomy was developed from (Axelrad, 1993) and (Boadway, 1979).


Abt Associates, Inc.                           3-40                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
        While lamentable, this lack of action is understandable given limits on the time and
  money that a homeowner can actually spend on obtaining information needed for many different
  decisions.  Even though homeowners, as parents,  may be deeply concerned about the  welfare
  of their children - a key target of exposure from lead contamination -  there are a host of other
  issues besides lead which affect their children's welfare and for which parents need information
  to make important decisions. These other information needs compete with the information needs
  of the lead abatement decision for scarce household resources. Given  how little abatement has
  been initiated by homeowners relative to the prevalence of the problem, the likelihood that there
  is insufficient demand for abatement and that information gaps contribute to this circumstance
  appears to be high.  In conclusion,  it appears that at least one condition associated with market
  failures holds and, consequently, that inefficiencies may characterize the market for lead testing
  and abatement.

        Before a final determination  can be made about the inefficiencies associated with the lack
  of information, the costs of spanning the information gaps must be considered. One of the more
  important unknown  variables in setting hazard levels under Section 403 is what approaches to
  making information available will actually get homeowners to test, to consider the abatement
 alternatives, and to undertake abatement where appropriate.  This analysis represents one step
 in shedding light on approaches that reduce possible inefficiencies.

        A central question is whether government intervention can make the right information
 available to increase the demand for abatement.  In attempting to answer this question, it is
 helpftil to consider the public good aspect of promulgating hazard levels. To the  extent the
 public  finds them credible and takes steps to measure lead contamination, the hazard  levels
 provide an independent benchmark for action, lessening at least part of the information needed
 to make an abatement decision.  As such, hazard levels can qualify as a public intermediate good
 since  they  can be  used simultaneously  by many  households  in  making  their abatement
 decisions.3  Whether the hazard levels are a public good  or not depends finally on whether the
 abatements induced by the hazard levels result in benefits exceeding the costs. If so, the hazard
 levels are a public good.  If not, they are a public bad. The analysis in this report addresses this
 issue directly by attempting to discriminate between the forms and magnitudes of hazard levels
 that lead to positive net benefits and those that do not.

       Other potential causes of market failure may characterize the persistence of lead
 contamination in residences.  By undertaking abatement,  the owner of a home creates positive
 externalities for any  occupants outside of his or her immediate family, such as  renters, if the
 owner is a landlord,  and subsequent owners  who are occupants of the home.  If these renters
 and subsequent owners are fully informed about the implications of lead contamination, the
 market  may adequately compensate  the original owner for undertaking lead abatement and no
 externality impedes the abatement decision.  If they are  not fully informed, then the original
 owner will not  be sufficiently compensated for services provided  to the renters and subsequent
 owners.  Under these circumstances, too few abatements will be undertaken.  It is difficult to
 measure how large this problem is since it requires information on the stock of knowledge about
 lead problems held by tenants and purchasers today and in the future.
             The term "public intermediate good" and its definition are adapted from Boadway, 1979.

Abt Associates. Inc.                           3-41                        ^ Januafy ]Q

-------
        Compounding the problem of undercompensation is a divergence between social and
 private discount rates, which matters since this analysis anticipates that occupants as much as
 fifty years in the future can potentially benefit from the abatement of a given house. Even if
 each renter  or subsequent  owner is willing to pay the full market value of the  externality
 provided by the original owner's undertaking lead abatement, it is likely that the private estimate
 of the present value of these future payments to the original owner will be smaller than the
 present  value based on the social rate of discount.   Consequently, by relying  on private
 decisions, fewer abatements will be undertaken.  The size of this effect could be estimated using
 the framework applied in this analysis but has not been conducted to date.

       This review suggests there is one or more market failures affecting decisions regarding
 the abatement of residential lead contamination.  The lack of perfect information is a primary
 culprit.  However, the evidence is not conclusive. The ultimate determination of a market
 failure  depends on  whether gains in efficiency  can be accomplished  by some form of
 intervention.  An allocation of resources is deemed inefficient if someone can be made better
 off without making someone else worse off.   That is a core question of this  analysis.  The
 discussion of risks from lead contamination does indicate  a substantial  potential for making
 individuals'  better  off by reducing  residential  exposures  from  soil,  dust,  and  paint.
 Consequently, one part of the definition of an inefficient allocation has been met. However, to
 determine whether the other part of the definition can  be satisfied depends on the outcome of
 the benefit-cost analysis itself.  If the benefits of reducing lead exposures  exceed all costs,  it is
 possible to accomplish  this without making others worse off.   The costs that have to be
 considered include the costs of getting the right people to decide to abate, to choose the right
 abatement, and to perform  and maintain the abatement in the expected manner as well  as the
 direct costs of testing and abatement.
Abt Associates, Inc.                           3-42                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 3.3   NEED FOR FEDERAL REGULATION

       In the Residential Lead-Based Paint Hazard Reduction Act of 1992 ("the Act"), the
 United States Congress identified the elimination of lead-based paint hazards as a national goal.
 Congress found that the Federal Government must take a leadership role in building the required
 infrastructure,  including  an informed  public, State and  local  delivery  systems, certified
 inspectors, contractors, and laboratories, trained workers  (§1002(8)).  By identifying what
 constitutes a  lead-based paint hazard (defined as paint, dust or soil conditions that would result
 in adverse human health effects), Section 403 creates a crucial portion of the integrated federal
 regulatory approach necessary to adequately inform the public of the dangers of lead-based paint,
 and to implement other portions of the Act that require mandatory action if a lead-based paint
 hazard exists.

 The proposed federal identification of lead-based paint hazards will provide guidance to states,
 localities and individuals in protecting citizen's rights. Such guidance will promote partnerships
 in developing the most cost-effective ways to address lead-based paint hazards.  The Act
 encourages the individual States to adopt the federal §403  regulations, as well  as federal
 regulations from other sections of the Act, to the specific conditions that exist in the States by
 utilizing existing State and local  programs.   Further, States have the option of imposing
 requirements which are more stringent than the federal procedures. Thus the States may respond
 to regional diversity  and  local social choice by building upon  the §403 identification while
 guaranteeing  the minimum rights of all citizens.

       The Act authorizes certain federal expenditures to partially achieve the national goal of
 eliminating lead-based paint hazards.  Authorized federal expenditures include federal grants for
 evaluating and reducing lead-based paint hazards in non-publicly owned or assisted housing, risk
 assessments and interim controls in federally assisted housing, and inspections and abatement
 of lead-based paint hazards  in all  federally owned  housing constructed prior to 1960.  The
 Section 403 identification of lead-based paint hazards is necessary to implement these federal
 expenditures  in a manner that develops the most promising cost effective methods.
Abt Associates, Inc.                           3-43                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 3.4   REGULATORY OPTIONS

       Four general classes of instalments are options for government intervention.  These are
 (1) information provision and labelling, (2) performance or technical standards, (3) bans or
 restrictions on use, and (4) economic incentives.  The first of these is most closely linked to the
 primary condition contributing to a market failure, as described in Section 3.2.  Consequently,
 directly addressing the lack of adequate information will be the focus of the discussion in this
 section, and in the analysis of this report.  Examples of how the other three classes of
 instruments could be applied are presented but only to illustrate their potential. Further analysis
 will be required to determine how viable they  are.

 3.4.1  Information Provision

       A  draft regulator's  guide on economic incentives under TSCA identifies three
 circumstances that  are particularly favorable to making the provision of information an
 appropriate  instrument for intervention (Eyraud, 1993).  The first circumstance - that there is
 a significant lack of information generating exposure problems - has already been identified as
 a strong likelihood.  To rectify this circumstance, a corollary condition has to be met. The new
 information has to be able to induce exposure-reducing behavior.  Information programs are
 appealing as a means of intervention in part because they do not impose direct burdens on the
 economy. One of the dangers, though, is that the absence of a direct burden will come at the
 expense of being ineffective. This does not have to be the case.   Collectively, environmental
 and other public health programs have amassed substantial experience in learning about what
 works and what does not in risk communication. This expertise will have to be tapped to render
 any information approach effective.

       The second circumstance favorable to effective information provision is one where the
 exposure is  not created by an externality beyond the exposed  individuals'  control.  In other
 words, the affected population  has to be able to put the information to good use.  While
 externalities between current abatement and future beneficiaries were identified  as a possible
 cause of market failure, these do not prevent information from  being effective.  For example,
 if a house is not abated over the next 30  years, at least the occupants at that future time can
 decide to undertake abatement if they have the right information to motivate their decision. This
 circumstance appears to apply to the exposures from lead in residential soil, dust, and paint.
 There is however at least  one major exception.  Financial constraints can prevent even the best
 informed household from taking effective steps to reduce exposure.  As homeowners, households
 may not be able to afford  abatement. As renters and buyers, they not be able to afford housing
 that has been abated.  It is important to note, however, that this hindrance is not unique to an
 information approach.  It is likely to affect other interventions to the same or greater degree.
Abt Associates, Inc.                          3-44                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
        The third circumstance favorable to the use of an information approach is one where
 other interventions would lead to greater and significant economic impacts. Although its effects
 are indirect (working through  changes in  behavior rather than by direct enforcement),  an
 information approach does create economic impacts.  Whether these  economic impacts' are
 greater or less  than  those  of  other  interventions is unknown  at this  time because other
 interventions have not been studied in  as much depth.

 Scope of Analysis

        This analysis focuses on the influence that a particular type of information - hazard levels
 - can have on the abatement decisions of homeowners.  Promulgating such hazard levels is one
 means of implementing Section 403 of TSCA, which calls for EPA to identify lead-based paint
 hazards,  lead-contaminated dust, and lead-contaminated soil.  One objective in promulgating
 such hazard levels is to fill part of the information gap that has  been linked to sluggish rates of
 abatement of lead-contaminated homes.  Specifically, these hazard levels are intended to indicate
 thresholds at which EPA recommends that certain forms of abatement take place. As such, they
 can lower the information costs for homeowners' making a decision about whether to abate and
 as a result increase the demand  for abatement. It is important to note that by providing  such
 hazard levels, EPA will not be eliminating the information costs altogether.  For example, the
 costs of  testing  for levels of lead  in  soil,  dust, and paint are still substantial.   These are
 considered in this analysis.  Also, any  public information campaign to motivate households to
 be concerned about and test for lead contamination (analogous possibly to the public campaign
 currently being waged for radon) will impose costs.  These have not been explicitly considered
 here.

        The potential form of the  hazard levels covers a wide range. At one extreme, the levels
 of action  would be set uniquely for each individual home, taking its circumstances into account
 to determine whether soil, dust,  and/or paint should be abated  and, if so,  how.  At the other
 extreme,  one hazard level would be set for each medium (soil, dust, and paint) for the entire
 nation. This analysis constructs  different decision rules that reflect each of these extremes.  A
 brief synopsis is provided here and greater detail in Chapter 6.

       The first decision rule considered in this analysis has the highest information requirement.
 The public is assumed to have access to the same information that was used in this analysis
 (e.g., blood lead  levels; reductions achievable from different abatements; the monetary values
 of these blood lead  reductions; abatement costs; and the levels of lead in soil, dust, and paint
 and the condition of paint in  the home).  Having the highest information  requirement has its
 rewards.  Called  the "voluntary  optimum," this rule generates  the highest net benefits of all
 decision rules evaluated since the information can be used to target abatement decisions so well.

       By providing guidance to households in the form of hazard levels at which abatement
 should be undertaken, EPA can lower the actual information costs for the household abatement
 decision.  In the other decision rules, households are assumed to have less  information overall
 and therefore less leeway to choose on their own, instead being induced by EPA's hazard levels
 to initiate abatements of certain types.  As a result, some households also make mistakes, such
 as abating when  a  benefit-cost analysis does  not show that it is warranted or abating  one
 medium, such as soil, when abating another, such as dust, would be more productive. It follows
Abt Associates, Inc.                           3-45
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 that the net benefits of these decision rales are not as high as those that can be achieved under
 the voluntary optimum,  where more information is available. What these rules have in their
 favor though is their simplicity.  The simpler the action levels, the less complicated is the
 decision for each household.  If one or more action  levels are exceeded,  then a particular
 medium should be abated.  At its simplest, one set of levels of action can be promulgated for
 the entire nation.

        These decision rules are of four types, reflecting varying degrees.   The first type of
 decision rule addressed paint condition. It assumes that all homes with non-intact paint will
 undertake paint abatement.  The second type of decision rule included this criterion as well as
 a hazard level for each of the three media that are addressed by this rule - soil, dust, and paint.
 These  are  labeled  "single-medium constrained"  rules.   The  third type  of decision rale
 encompasses hazard levels for two media, as well as condition. The fourth type of decision rale
 addresses all three media and condition. This analysis compares the net benefits of each of these
 decision rales for the abatements that are actually induced by the respective hazard levels.
 3.4.2  Other Regulatory Options

       Other regulatory instruments may also be effective for addressing the market failures that
 have led to inadequate abatement of lead.  These alternative instruments have not been examined
 to the same extent as the primary instrument considered -information provision. Suggestions for
 alternatives that might be investigated further are provided in Exhibit 3-18.   The list is meant
 to illustrative rather than exhaustive, particularly where economic incentives are concerned. The
 feasibility and advisability of these alternatives could vary widely.
Abt Associates, Inc.                           3-46                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                      Exhibit 3-18
                             Other Regulatory Alternatives
       Type of Instrument
                 Possible Application
    Labelling
 Section 1018 of the Residential Lead-Based Paint
 Hazard Reduction Act of 1992 requires the disclosure of
 lead-based paint or any known paint hazards in the sale
 of target housing (any housing constructed prior  to
 1978).  This provision could be extended to provide
 information on soil and dust hazards, not just paint, at
 the time of sale of any housing, not just target housing.
    Technical and
    Performance Standards
Hazard levels could be enforced through performance or
technical requirements. Owners of homes where
children are present would, for example, have to keep
paint in good condition, and reduce and keep soil and
dust contamination below the hazard levels.  Technical
standards could specify exactly what abatements are
necessary if hazard levels are exceeded.
    Bans and Restrictions of
    Use
Restrictions could be placed on the access of young
children to homes where lead contamination is of
concern.  These restrictions could include exclusion
from occupying such homes or from spending extensive
amounts of time in them, or prohibitions from  accessing
particular areas, such as rooms with paint in
deteriorated condition or bare play areas outdoor where
soil contamination is high.
    Economic Incentives
A quota could be established for the numbers of homes
allowed to have excess lead contamination.  The quota
could be allocated by a system of marketable
allowances.  Homes without allowances would  have to
undertake abatement or accept restrictions on their
accessibility to young children.
Abt Associates, Inc.
          3-47
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 3.5   REFERENCES

 Axelrad, D.  1993. Guidance on the Preparation of Economic Analyses and Regulatory Impact
       Analyses in OPFT.  Regulatory Impacts Branch,  Office of Pollution Prevention and
       Toxics, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Washington, D.C., January, pp. 26-27.

 Baltrop, D. 1966. The Prevalence of Pica. American Journal of Disabled Children, 112:116,
       as cited in HUD, 1990.

 Roadway, R.W.  1979. Public Sector Economics.  Little, Brown and Company (Inc.), Boston
       MA, pp. 29-43.

 Bureau of Census, U.S. Department of Commerce, 1991. Annual Housing Survey Components
       of Inventory Change:  1973 to 1983.

 Bureau of Census, U.S. Department of Commerce, 1992a.  Population Projections of the United
       States  by Age, Sex,  Race and Hispanic Origin:   1992 to 2050.  Current Population
       Reports P2S-1092.

 Bureau of Census, U.S. Department of Commerce, 19925.  Statistical Abstract of the United
       States.  112th Edition.

 Centers for Disease Control (CDC) U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, 1991.
       Strategic Plan for the Elimination of Childhood Lead Poisoning.  February.

 Dietrich, K.N., Krafft, K.M., Shukla, R., Bomschein,  R.L., Succop, P.A.  1987.  The
       neurobehavioral effects  of prenatal and early postnatal lead exposure.  In:  Schroeder,
       S.R., ed. Toxic Substances and Mental Retardation:  Neurobehavioral Toxicology and
       Teratology.  Washington DC:  American Association of Mental Deficiency, 1987: 71-
       95 (Monograph No. 8).

 Elias, R. 1993.  US  EPA, Office of Research  and  Development. Personal communication
       through Karen Hogan, US EPA Office of Pollution Prevention  and Toxics, July 7.

 Eyraud, J.  1993.  Economic Incentives  Under TSCA:   A Regulator's Guide.   Volume I.
       Review Draft.  For the U.S.  Environmental Protection Agency, Office of Pollution
       Prevention and Toxics, Regulatory Impacts Branch. Washington, D.C., February, pp
       3-12.

 Lewis and Clark County Health Department, Montana Department of Health and Environmental
       Sciences, Center for Disease Control (Public Health Service, U.S. Department of Health
       and Human Services), and U.S. Environmental Protection Agency.  1986.  East Helena,
       Montana Child Lead Study, Summer 1983.  Final Report, 36.

Madhavan,  S.,  Rosenman, K.D., and Shehata, T.   1989.   Lead in Soil: Recommended
       Maximum Permissible Levels.  Environmental Research, 49: 136-142.
Abt Associates, Inc.                         3-48                      Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 Mahaffey, K. 1993. US EPA, Office of Research and Development.  Personal communication
       through Karen Hogan, US EPA Office of Pollution Prevention and Toxics, July 7.

 National Association of Home Builders of the United States (NAHB),  1992.  Forecast of
       Housing Activity.  November.

 Schwartz, J.   1993a.   US EPA,  Office  of Policy Planning and Evaluation.   Personal
       Communication, April 29.

 Schwartz, J. 1993b. Beyond LOEL's, p Values and Vote Counting:  Methods for Looking at
       the Shapes and Strengths of Associations. NeuroToxicology, 14(2-3): 237-246.

 Schwartz, J., Levin, R. 1991.  The Risk of Lead Toxicity in Homes with Lead Paint Hazard.
       Environmental Research, 54:  1-7.

 Shannon, MW. Graef, J.W. 1992. Lead Intoxication in Infancy. Pediatrics, 89(1): 87-90.

 U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD). 1990. Comprehensive and
       Workable Plan for the Abatement of Lead-Based Paint in Privately Owned Housing:
       Report to Congress.  Washington DC. December.

 U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 1991.  Guidance Manual for Site-Specific Use
       of the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency Lead Model (Draft).  December.3.5
Abl Associates, Inc.                         3-49                     Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                       4.  COSTS
 4.1    METHOD FOR COST ANALYSIS

        The general method used for the cost analysis was to develop a unit cost for the testing
 and abatement of lead in each medium  (dust, paint and soil) for a single house and then apply
 this unit cost to the housing population to be abated. Abatements vary in effectiveness, duration
 and cost.  To explore these variations, ten abatement strategy scenarios were considered along
 with the option not to abate. Abatements occurred just prior to the birth of the first child in a
 home.  All cost results are presented in present value terms. Nominal costs from several studies
 have been used.  Because of the narrow time range of the data around the base year (1987-1993
 for a 1990 base year) and because the variation caused by changes in money value over time was
 within the uncertainty of the estimates, presenting the costs in constant dollars would have little
 effect.  The next section describes the data available on the costs of testing and abatement for
 lead  in dust, paint and soil.   Section  4.3 shows a sample cost calculation  and Section 4.4
 presents results.


 4.2   DATA

       To carry  out  the analysis, unit  costs  for testing and high-end and low-end1 levels of
 abatement of lead  in dust,  paint and soil were estimated from the available data.  Primary
 sources of the data were the "Comprehensive and Workable Plan for the Abatement of Lead-
 Based Paint in Privately Owned Housing, Report to Congress" (HUD, 1990),  the results from
 the Urban Soil Lead Abatement Demonstration Projects,  and selected interviews with lead testing
 and abatement firms as  well as landscapes, commercial cleaning services and hazardous waste
 disposal firms. The data were generally point estimates  and in some cases represented costs for
 somewhat  different services.  For example, some estimates included  relocation of the house
 occupants during abatement while others did not.   Frequently the exact services included in a
 single estimate were not listed.  This  was particularly  true of paint abatements where the
 information on the quantity of paint removed and  the post-abatement testing were not clearly
 described.   The analysis presents reasonable  high  and  low cost estimates for each abatement
 scenario by combining the estimates obtained from these  sources as described below. A medium
 value is also presented.  In general this value is the mean of the high and low values.2  The
 relative merits of each abatement depend not only on the costs  of the abatement itself but also
 on  its effectiveness and duration.  Again information from the sources  listed above  were
 combined with the analyst's best judgment to create an estimate. These aspects of abatement
 (cost, effectiveness and  duration) are discussed separately below for each medium. The  costs
       The terms high-end and low-end refer to the level of abatement activity taking place.  For each level high,
medium and low costs have been estimated that reflects the range of costs for a particular activity level.

       The only exception occurs for the medium exterior paint abatement cost. The $5,000 value used was based
on abating a duplex and was considered more accurate than taking the mean of the high ($10,000 for a single family
home) and low ($3,000 for a single unit of a multifamily dwelling) estimates.

Abt Associates, Inc.                            4-1                        Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
  of abating different media are then combined for each of the scenarios to provide a total cost for
  each abatement strategy.

  4.2.1  Testing and Abatement Costs of Lead in Dust

  Dust Testing

         The few dust testing costs that have been reported in the literature are highly variable
  This is probably due to differences in protocol such as the number of samples and the method
  of sampling.  The Agency is in the process of developing its own dust testing standards  The
  current draft standards call for, at a minimum, collection of two dust samples in each of four
  rooms and additional samples if the paint is in poor condition. Further samples are required in
  common areas. Since there is no standard testing protocol, we combined the draft protocol with
  information obtained from lead abatement firms on the cost of testing.  One reputable firm in
  New England reported a cost of inspection of $128 (for paint,soil and dust) plus $15 per sample
  analyzed (Ulluci, 1993). Combining one-third  of the $128 inspection cost with the testing costs
  of nine samples results in a $178 dust testing estimate. The calculation is shown below.


                             0.33 x $128 +  9 x  $15 = $178               Equation 4.1

  A further survey of three lead inspection firms in the Mid-west gave an average labor estimate
  of six hours per complete inspection of lead in  paint, soil and dust at about $40 per hour  The
  calculation  for dust assumes that one third of that labor  was needed to  inspect for dust  A
  second estimate of the total cost of dust testing was calculated using this value for inspection and
  the mid-point of the range of sampling analysis costs,  $12-27, reported by nine Minnesota lead
 analysis firms.  The resulting total testing cost, with  ten  samples required, is $280 as shown
 below.


                              2 x $40 +  10  x $20  = $280                Equation 4.2

 Averaging the two calculated values ($178 -I- $280)/2  yields $230 for an estimate of total dust
 testing costs.

       The calculated testing estimates are very uncertain.  The method used for sampling the
 dust was not recorded for any of the firms and could be an important  cost factor.  In addition
 the values calculated were based on a limited review of the  costs of testing. It is also likely that
 a range of quality coexists with  the range of price and some quality control monitoring would
 be necessary in any dust testing  scenario.

 Dust Abatement

       Cost. The cost of lead dust abatement depends  on the thoroughness of the cleaning and
 whether rugs, furniture and duct work are replaced.  Two sets of estimates are  available  The
 first is from  the Urban Soil Lead Abatement Demonstration Project cities which reported costs
 of $134-458  in Boston (Weitzman et al., 1992) and $1,216 in Cincinnati (Clark and Bornschein
Abt Associates, Inc.                           4_2
                                                                   Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 1993).  The second is from the HUD Report to Congress which estimated a range of dust
 abatement costs from $505-730 per cleanup (HUD, 1990).  For the high-end abatement option,
 the Cincinnati estimate was used as the high cost estimate while the mid-point of the Boston
 range, $300, was used as the lower value. The mean of the two was the medium cost value as
 shown in Exhibit 4-1.  The abatement  included moving families  off-site while the floors,
 woodwork, window wells and  some furniture were vacuumed with a high-efficiency particle
 accumulator vacuum.  Hard surfaces were also wiped with a wet cloth following vacuuming.

       The low-end dust abatement strategy is defined as an additional house cleaning, including
 general dusting, vacuuming, cleaning bathrooms and wiping window sills.  The low cost estimate
 of $38 was based on an informal survey of cleaning services-an estimate of about $25 per hour
 for cleaning a 3-room apartment in an hour and a half (Rohmer, 1993). The high cost estimate
 was calculated assuming a six room house at the same hourly rate for a cost of $75 per cleaning.
 The medium cost estimate, $57, was the mean of the high and low cost values.

       Effectiveness.  The effectiveness  of dust abatement depends on  the circumstances in
 which it is used. A single cleaning, the nonrecurrent dust abatement scenario, will reduce the
 dust level to the lower of the dust level reported in the survey or the dust level calculated from
 the soil and paint lead levels as described in Chapter 3.  Alternatively, recurrent dust abatement
 is assumed to  reduce the dust lead level to 100 parts per million (ppm).

       Duration. The duration of the dust abatement also depends on the circumstance in which
 it is used.  If there are no external sources of lead the high-end dust abatement is assumed to
 be permanent.  If there are external sources of lead the high-end dust abatement is assumed to
 be done every ten years and the low-end dust abatement is assumed to be done every month to
 maintain the abated level.
4.2.2  Testing and Abatement Costs for Lead-based Faint

Interior Paint Testing

       The cost of testing for lead-based paint depends both on the type of testing done and the
number of samples taken.  The Agency is currently developing a testing protocol to standardize
the number and type of tests required, and once the standards are finalized, variability based on
these factors will be  reduced.  A typical  testing plan requires  a  visual inspection of paint
condition and determination  of the lead content of painted surfaces by either in situ analysis
using a portable x-ray fluorescence (XRF) spectrum analyzer or by off-site laboratory analysis
of paint chip samples.  X-ray fluorescence analysis has the advantage of being both lower in cost
and  non-destructive when compared with  laboratory paint  chip analysis.   However, XRF
readings are not as accurate as laboratory analysis (HUD, 1990).

       Few paint testing costs are reported  in the literature.  The lead-based paint testing
protocol  for the Housing and Urban Development Department's  1989 lead  in housing survey
reported  a $375 cost per unit (HUD, 1990).  The cost included five interior readings and  five
exterior  readings  (using a portable XRF  spectrum analyzer), a visual inspection, detailed
estimation of the amount of paint surface and an interview  with the  owner.  The $375 value

Abt Associates, Inc.                           4-3                        Draft, January 10,  1994

-------
                                                              EXHIBIT 4-1

                                           Summary of Abatement Costs for Lead in Dust*
Dust Abatement
Activity
Level
High
Low
Activities
Families moved off-site, hard
surfaces (floors, woodwork, window
wells and some furniture) vacuumed
with a high-efficiency particle
accumulator (HEPA) vacuum. Hard
surfaces were also wiped with a wet
cloth (an oil treated rag used on
furniture) following vacuuming
One additional standard house
cleaning per month including general
dusting, vacuuming, cleaning
bathrooms and wiping window sills

Cost
Estuuflte
Level
High
Medium
Low
High
Medium
Low

Costs
$ Value
$1,216
Recommend using $1200''
$750
$134-458
Recommend using $300°
$75 Based on $25/hr for a 6 room house
$57
$38
1 .5 hours for a 3 room apartment at $25/hour
Source
Clark et al., 1993
Avenge of high
and low
Weitzman ct ftl.
1992
Rohmer, 1993
Average of high
and low
Rohmer, 1993
Hfotfanen

based on scenario. For a single
cleaning, the dust level is the
lower of the HUD reported dust
and that calculated for the soil
and XRF levels. For recurrent
cleanings, the dust level is
reduced to 100 ppm.
(Only used as maintenance of the
high-end dust abatement)
Dun**,
PornuMiil
if no lead
source ia
present
IMMMtk
•nDnui
    'Sources for cost estimates are listed in the fifth column of the table.
    ^Using only two significant figures for the estimate.
    'Midpoint of the range rounded to two significant figures.
Abt Associates, Inc.
4-4
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
  reported may thus overestimate the tnie value of interior lead-based paint testing alone because of the
  inclusion of detailed inspection and cataloging of the amount of paint present and the collection of
  exterior samples. A reputable contractor in New England quoted a price of $55 for 25 XRF readings
  and $128 for sample collection and travel as part of a complete lead inspection (Ullucci, 1993)  If one-
  third of the collection and travel is attributed to the lead paint inspection (assuming soil and dust account
  for the remaining two-thirds) the total inspection and testing costs will be about $100 as calculated
  below if 25 XRF readings are taken.


                                  0.33 x $128 + $55 « $100                     Equation 4.3

 As mentioned in Section 4.2.1, a survey of three lead inspection firms in the Mid-west gave an average
 labor estimate of a six hours per complete inspection of lead in paint, soil and dust at about $40 per
 hour.  This information was combined with sample analysis costs from a list of Minnesota de-leading
 contractors (primarily from the Minneapolis/ St. Paul area) that showed a range of lead paint sample
 analysis costs of $18-27 per sample.  An estimated  lead testing cost of $360 per house was calculated
 by assuming that sampling costs are $23, the mid-point of the range, and that twelve samples were taken
 and analyzed (based on a protocol of two per room for four rooms as is likely in the EPA protocol and
 four in the entryways or common areas). In addition, it was assumed that lead paint sampling labor is
 one-third of the total inspection labor. The value is calculated below.


                                 2 x $40 + 12 x $23 « $360                    Equation 4.4

        Our final estimated cost of $230 is the average of the estimated costs from the New England and
 Minnesota data, ($100 + $360)/2 =  $230.  The HUD cost  value was not included  because of the
 additional cataloging and interviewing it involved. Lead abatement inspections are still in their infancy
 and with more competition, the price could be  lowered; however, as standards are instituted, the price
 may rise because of training costs and performance requirements.  In addition, if the lead paint testing
 is not earned out in conjunction with inspections of other media, the cost of travel and collection could
 nse.  The variation in costs is likely to be large  given the range of house sizes and the possible variation
 in the number of samples taken.

 Exterior Paint Testing

       The cost  of testing for exterior lead-based paint was estimated at $115, half the value of the
 interior lead-based paint testing. Because exterior lead-based paint covered  surfaces tend to be larger
 and less varied than interior surfaces, fewer samples would probably be needed to establish the extent
 of lead-based paint.  In this analysis it is assumed that half as many samples are taken outside as are
 taken inside. Six samples are taken, one for each  of the four sides of a  house and  two for added
 features such as porches and doors, so the sampling time and testing costs should be approximately half
 the value of interior lead-based paint testing which requires twelve samples.  Four environmental lead
 analysis firms were contacted to confirm the two to one ratio of interior to exterior paint testing  Only
 two of the firms conduct this type of testing on private homes and both use a ratio of approximately
two-to one. Gene Sparrow of Advanced R&D, St. Paul, Minnesota takes about 12 interior samples and
between 4 and 8  exterior samples.  Scott Askew of Nova Environmental Services, Incorporated takes
 15-20 samples inside and 7-8 samples outside.
   Abt Associates, Inc.                           4-5
                                                                      Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 Interior Faint Abatement

        Cost.  Similar to the cost of testing, the estimated cost of interior lead paint abatement can vary
 widely. Some of the variation is caused by differences in the extent of abatement.   For example,
 replacing the windows is less expensive than removing all the molding, doors and wall paint.  Some
 of the variation is due to the size of the house and some is due to regional cost variation.  The average
 cost reported by local abatement programs for lead abatement is $2,100 in 1989 dollars, accoiding to
 a Center for Disease Control (CDC) report based on local projects that included abatement of common
 areas and exterior when necessary, costs of materials, labor insurance, overhead, woricer protection and
 cleanup (CDC, 1991).  The estimated costs in  the HUD Report to Congress are much higher, except
 in the "Units with Interior Lead-Based Paint (LBP) Only" category, which estimates $1,808 per unit
 of removal. HUD also found that over 50 percent of all housing units with lead-based paint could be
 abated by removal for under $2,500 per unit.  The Boston Globe reported the average cost of a de-
 leading job for a single unit in Massachusetts  as $3,450 in  1990 where valid methods of  abatement
 include stripping, removal or enclosure of the lead paint (Carroll, 1993).  Based on  the values for
 interior paint abatement estimated in a Michigan grant proposal to the CDC, the complete abatement
 cost estimates range from $16,000 per unit for  a ten unit apartment building to $23,000 per unit for a
 single family house. The proposal also reports an average cost of $15,000 for units abated by Maryland
 and Minnesota under their state plans.  No distinction is made on this last  value between interior and
 exterior lead-based paint abatement. Telephone calls to a small sample of de-leading contractors in the
 United States produced a range of estimates from $4,000 to $12,000 for a complete interior lead paint
 abatement.  As part of the Boston study of the effects of soil abatement, 46  homes were de-leaded with
 a  reported  average cost of $7,500 for interior paint de-leading.  If the  costs of moving, storage,
 alternative housing, inspections, monitoring and clearance samples are added, the costs could rise to
 $10,000-$10,500 (Weitzman, 1992).  A typical interior lead-based paint abatement in Maryland was
 reported to  be about $12,000 although there is considerable variation (Morris, 1993).  Exhibit 4-2
 summarizes the various cost estimates for interior paint abatement.

       The high-end paint abatement option for our model is complete removal of lead-based paint
 including full abatement of windows, doors, woodwork and walls plus a high-end dust abatement. The
 range of abatement costs presented above reflects differences  in house size, quantity of lead paint
 present and abatement technique used.  For this  analysis we developed high, medium and low costs for
 the high-end abatement activities. Typical low cost for high-end abatement  was $7,500 while $12,000
 was considered representative of recent high cost experience in complete interior lead paint removal
 including disposal of debris as a non-hazardous waste (excluding dust abatement).  The medium cost
 ($9,750) reflects the mean of high and low values for high-end paint abatement.  If dust abatement
 (Section 4.2.1) is included, the total low, medium, and high cost high-end paint abatements are $8,250,
 $10,500, and $12,750 respectively. High-end dust abatement is included in this calculation to ensure
 that the full abatement effectiveness is achieved. These values are shown in Exhibit 4-3.

      While complete removal of all lead paint represents a high-end abatement, replacement of
 windows reflects a typical partial abatement.  Paint on windows is preferentially prone to peeling and
 flaking due to movement of the  sash and the increased exposure to sunlight  and weathering.  The cost
of replacing a window ranges from $131 for an aluminum window to $262 for a wooden sliding window
 (R.S. Means, 1987). An informal interview with Vance Morris of Maryland's Department of Housing
and Community Development confirmed $200 as an average value for a window replacement (Morris,
 1993).  Information on the average number of windows per house is difficult to obtain since this

   Abt Associates, Inc.                          4-6                       Draft, January 10. 1994

-------
                                    EXHIBIT 4-2



                Summary of Interior Lead-based Faint Abatement Costs
Cost
$1,808
$2,100
$2,500
$3,450
$4000-$12,000
$7,500
$10,000-$10,500
$12,000
$15,000
$16,000 per unit
for a ten unit
apartment
$23,000 for a
single family
house
Activities Covered
Removal of lead-based paint in units with
only interior lead-based paint
Average lead abatement cost reported by
local abatement programs
Value at which 50% of all housing units with
lead-based paint could be abated by removal
Average cost of a de-leading job for a single
unit in Massachusetts in 1990 by stripping,
removal or enclosure
Complete lead abatement, method
unspecified
Average cost of de-leading 46 homes in
Boston
Average cost of de-leading 46 homes in
Boston if moving, storage, alternative
housing, inspections, monitoring and
clearance samples are added
Typical interior lead-based paint abatement
in Maryland, method unspecified
Stated as average cost for unit abated in
Maryland and Minnesota, may include
exterior paint abatement as well
Interior lead-based paint abatement cost
estimates
Source
HUD, 1990
CDC, 1991
HUD, 1990
Carroll, 1993
Sample of U.S. de-
leading contractors
Weitzman, 1992
Weitzman, 1992
Morris, 1993
Michigan, 1991
Michigan, 1991
Abt Associates, Inc.
4-7
                                                                 Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                                                       EXHIBIT 4-3
                                                         Summary of Abatement Costs for Lead in Paint*


Activity
Level
High
Low

Activities
Full abatement of windows, doors,
woodwork and walls, includes mean
high-level dust abatement necessary to
ensure abatement to effectiveness
level postulated values do not include
disposal of abatement debris as a
hazardous waste
Replace 15 windows @ $200 each
plus mean high-level dust abatement
to ensure abatement to effectiveness
postulated
Replace 10 windows ® $200 each
plus mean high-level dust abatement
to ensure abatement to effectiveness
postulated
Replace 5 windows @ $200 each,
plus mean high level dust abatement
to ensure abatement to effectiveness
postulated

Cost
Estimate
Level
High
Medium
Low
High
Medium
Low
Costs
$ Value
Elements: $12,000b + $750°
Total: $12,750
Elements: $9.750* + $750°
Total: $10,500
Elements: $7,500* + $750°
Total: $8,250
Elements: $3,000* + $750°
Total: $3,750
Elements: $2,000* + $750°
Total: $2,750
Elements: $1000h + $750°
Total: $1,750
Source
Morris, 1993
Average of high
and low estimates
Weitzman, 1992
Morris, 1993
irf!fn«i*tV«Mnn»
ttllCCDVCBCSS
Abated to a paint
lead level
removal of all
paint plus
removing all the
paint ingestion for
pica children
Abated to a dust
lead level that is
91. 4% of the
original dust level
plus removing ell
the paint ingestion
for pice children
(See Section 4.2.2)
Duration
•J^______»
rGllllUWIH
Permanent (for
windows)
                                            snown in me mm co limn 01 me tame.
             0  High-cost estimate for High-end interior lead-based paint abatement.
             c  Average-cost estimate for High-end lead dust abatement.
             d  Mediu
                         stesbi
! for High-end interior
lead-hiued
                                                                paint abatement.
             e Low-cost estimate for High-end interior lead-based paint abatement.
             f High-cost estimate for Low-end interior lead-based paint abatement.
             > Medium-cost estimate for Low-end interior lead-based paint abatement.
             h Low-cost estimate for Low-end interior lead-based paint abatement.
Abt Associates, Inc.
                   4-8
                                 Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 information is included in neither the American Housing Survey nor the decennial census.  The low
 medium and high estimates were calculated using 5, 10, and IS windows3, respectively; the resulting
 overall cost estimates of low-end paint abatement are $1000, $2,000 and $3,000. Including high-end
 dust abatement brings the totals to $1,750, $2,750, and $3,750. The equation is shown below.


                                   LPAC = Wx $200 + $750                      Equation 4.5
where:
       LPAC =     Low-end Paint Abatement Cost, and
       W     =     Number of windows.

The Michigan proposal estimates a value of between $3000 and $6500 for replacement of windows in
one unit of a ten unit apartment and a single family dwelling, respectively. The lower costs are used
for the modelling effort with the understanding that the actual value could vary greatly depending on
the type  and number of windows replaced.  These values do not explicitly assume debris disposal costs
but  if the  waste is considered non-hazardous its disposal cost is within  the uncertainty of the cost
estimate. The Agency has not yet made a decision on whether paint abatement waste will be exempted
from the Resource  Conservation and  Recovery  Act hazardous  waste definitions.   Under current
regulation, only those portions of the waste that fail the Toxicity Characteristic Leaching Procedure
(TCLP)  for lead are  considered  hazardous waste.4  Disposal costs  depend  on the quantity  being
discarded.  If each abatement produced an average of 217 pounds of hazardous waste, as was generated
per housing unit in the Housing and Urban Development abatement demonstration project, and cost the
reported  $255 to discard, the paint abatement costs would increase between two and nine percent
depending  on whether the low-end or high-end abatement scenario was chosen (US EPA, 1992a).

       Effectiveness.  The removal of all the lead-based paint in a home (the high-end paint abatement
option) was assumed to have an effectiveness equivalent to eliminating the paint contribution to lead dust
as well as  removing the possibility of high blood lead levels resulting from pica (the consumption of
non-food items). However, little data are available regarding the effectiveness of abatement techniques.
The HUD  demonstration  study did conduct follow-up on lead paint abatement effectiveness but the
          Personal communication with Gopaul Ahluwalia at the National Association of Home Builders, 1993. Mr.
   Ahluwalia estimated the average number of windows in a new single family home (17) and the average number per
   unit in a new multifamily apartment building (9) based on a recent construction-material-usage data base. There
   are two trends in home building that need to be considered before using these estimates as the number of windows
   present in homes built prior to 1980 (our population of interest for lead abatement).  The first is that new homes
   are larger now than in the past and second, homes are currently built with more windows to increase light in the
   house.  No quantitative information was available about the latter trend but the former trend was compensated for
   by multiplying the 1993 average number of windows by the ratio of the avenge square feet per single family home
   in 1980 compared to that estimated for 1993 (1600 sq. ft./2100 sq. ft.) resulting in an estimate of 13 windows per
   average single family home and 7 windows per unit for a multifamily dwelling built in 1980. The range investigated
   in the model 5-15 brackets these estimates.  Obviously, very large single family homes can have many more
   windows than the reasonable high value of 15 used in this analysis.

      Personal communication with Rajani Joglekar, Office of Solid Waste and Emergency Response,  US EPA, 1993.

   Abt Associates, Inc.                            4-9                        Draft. January 10. 1994

-------
 resulting values are reported as dust lead loadings which are not directly translatable into the dust lead
 concentration values used in our model.

        Window replacement was estimated to contribute 8.6 percent of the benefits that would accrue
 from abatement by removal.  The dust level is directly tied to the benefits thus  the post  window
 abatement dust level is 91.4 percent (100 - 8.6 percent) of the original dust level. This value was based
 on a calculation from the HUD survey data that showed about 8.6 percent of the lead-based paint
 accessible  to children was on windows.   This value may  underestimate  the effectiveness of the
 abatement  in homes where only the windows have lead-based paint or contribute to the lead dust levels.
 However,  the value may overestimate the effectiveness in houses with a large amount of accessible lead
 paint in places other than windows. In addition, the threat of elevated blood lead levels due to pica was
 removed from homes that had window replacement.

        Duration.  Removal of lead-based paint from a house results in permanent abatement as long
 as all the paint was removed as postulated in the high-end option.  There should be no further lead
 contribution from interior paint under this option.  In the low-end option where the windows were
 replaced, there  is also  permanent removal of  a portion of lead-based  paint.   Thus, the  overall
 assumption is permanent duration of paint abatement.

 Exterior Faint Abatement

       Cost.  The cost of exterior lead-based paint abatement depends on many factors including the
 size of the  house, whether or not the dwelling is a multi-unit abode and the method of abatement. The
 estimates for low, medium and high costs were obtained from  the Michigan report.  The report listed
 costs  of re-siding for a unit of an apartment complex, a duplex, and a single family home, as $3,000,
 $5,000  and $10,000 respectively; these values were taken as low, medium  and high exterior paint
 abatement cost estimates (Michigan, 1991).  The HUD Report to Congress shows exterior abatement
 costs  for homes that have only exterior lead-based paint as $2,841  for encapsulation and $4,791 for
 removal. However, if the costs quoted in HUD for abating interior lead-based paint are subtracted from
 the costs of abating units with both interior and exterior lead-based paint, the cost of abating exterior
 lead-based  paint is estimated to be $6,600.  While the latter value may overestimate  the cost because
 some  of the difference may be due to increased  interior lead-based paint abatement  costs, it reflects
 some of the variation among homes. The Boston experience with de-leading the interiors of 46 homes,
 as reported in Weitzman, is $5,700 per  home (Weitzman, 1992).  These values confirm the range of
 values chosen as our estimates.

      Effectiveness.  Abatement of exterior lead-based paint in this analysis is used only to ensure that
 the soil abatement effectiveness projected below (in Section 4.2.3) is  achieved. As a consequence, the
 effectiveness is not independent of the soil abatement value. However the contribution of exterior lead-
 based  paint to  soil has been assumed to be eliminated by the abatement as described in Exhibit 4.4.

      Duration. Exterior lead-based paint abatement is assumed to be permanent because all paint has
been removed.
   Abt Associates, Inc.                          4-10                      Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 4.2.3 Testing and Abatement Costs of Lead in Soil

 Soil Testing

       As with paint, soil testing costs can vary considerably based on the number of samples taken,
 the method of analysis used and the region of the country.  The cost of soil sampling reported by
 Baltimore in the Urban Soil Lead Abatement Demonstration Project is $825 for the 30 samples that
 were taken and analyzed for each house (Farrell, 1993).  The HUD survey took only nine samples per
 house but did not report the cost of sampling (HUD, 1990). The Agency is in the process of developing
 a standardized testing protocol. For the purposes of this study a four sample protocol was adopted,
 based on two composite dripline samples and two play area samples. If there is more than one play
 area, then the sampling cost would rise.  Estimated costs are based on two data sources. The first is
 a reliable lead contracting firm in New England that provided information indicating that each soil
 sample analysis costs $16 and overall inspection costs $128 for paint, lead and soil  (as discussed in
 Section 4.2.1).  By  assuming that one-third of the inspection time  is devoted  to soil sampling and
 assuming four soil samples are taken, the soil testing costs are about $106 as shown below.


                               0.33 x $128  + 4 x $16 = $106                   Equation 4.6

 The second data source is a list of laboratories and consultants in Minnesota that provide environmental
 lead analysis. This list shows a range of $12-32 for sample analysis costs.  Assuming two hours of
 labor (at $40 per hour) for inspection and sampling of soil, and analysis of four samples at $22 each,
 (the mid-point of the range), an estimate of $170 for soil testing results is calculated below.


                                 2 x $40 +  4 x $22 * $170                    Equation 4.7

 We used the average of the two calculated values, ($106+170)72 = $138, as the soil testing cost. The
 sampling for Baltimore was not included in the estimate because we lacked information on how the
 analysis was conducted.  However, the wide range of the estimates suggests that further investigation
 may be warranted.

 Soil Abatement

       Cost.  The costs of soil abatement are tied to the area treated, the method used and whether or
 not the waste  is considered hazardous under the Resource Conservation and Recovery Act (RCRA).
 Residential soil abatement is a relatively new industry and no standards have been established on what
 constitutes a  complete abatement.   The  three  participants  in the Urban Soil  Lead Abatement
 Demonstration Project, (Boston, Baltimore, and Cincinnati) provided costs for a high-end abatement
 process.  The procedure involved removal of six  inches of top soil, installation of a  barrier (Boston
 only), disposal of the contaminated soil as non-hazardous waste and replacement with new soil with less
 than 150 ppm  lead (or less than 50 ppm in Baltimore and Cincinnati) (Elias, 1993).  The costs ranged
 from $2,400 per property in Cincinnati, to $4,896 per property in Baltimore, to $6,600 and $9,600 per
property  under two separate contracts in Boston (Bias, 1992).  The higher of the two Boston studies
 was chosen as the high representative of the costs of high-end residential soil abatement because of the
use of the barrier.  Because simultaneous dust abatement is necessary to achieve full effectiveness for

   Abt Associates, Inc.                          4-11                       Draft, January 10. 1994

-------
 soil abatement, this value was combined with the high-end dust abatement cost, described in Section
 4.2.1, for a total of $10,350.  The lower cost estimate used the Baltimore value of $4,896, which,
 including high-end dust abatement sums to $5,646.  The Baltimore study was preferred in this instance
 to the Cincinnati  study because the latter study primarily abated playgrounds rather than residential
 lawns.  Exhibit 4-4 summarizes the soil abatement cost information.

       In certain cases, three other costs were added to the high-end soil abatement.  The first  is the
 cost of exterior paint abatement if the house has an exterior XRF reading greater than  1 mg/cm2.  The
 exterior paint abatement costs  have been described above.  Because exterior lead-based paint is a
 primary source of lead soil contamination, it is necessary to abate the exterior paint to maintain the low
 soil lead levels achieved by soil abatement.  Two additional costs are incurred if the soil must be
 transported and disposed as a hazardous waste under RCRA.  Soil is considered hazardous if it fails the
 Toxicity Characteristic Leaching Procedure (TCLP)  for lead.  Many  factors affect the leaching
 characteristics of lead in soil including the soil type and pH.  As a conservative estimate we assumed
 soil with lead levels greater than 2000 ppm will fail the test. Thus houses with soils that fail the TCLP
 will incur the additional soil disposal and transportation costs. Based on an interview with Chemical
 Waste Management the cost of stabilization and landfilling of lead contaminated soil is between $230
 and $275 per ton (Donegan, 1993).

       The high cost option uses the quantity of soil removed from lawns under the 1989 Boston
 contract  (41  cubic yards)  (Weitzman, 1992). The soil abatements from the Demonstration Project
 already include the cost of disposing of the soil as a non-hazardous waste.  To avoid double counting
 the disposal the cost of $250 per ton for hazardous waste was reduced by $35 per ton for landfilling
 non-hazardous waste, which results in a cost of $215 per ton. The $215  per ton is multiplied by 41
 cubic yards and by 1.3 tons per cubic yard for a total disposal  cost of $11,460.  For the lower cost
 estimate, the Baltimore experience of an average of 14.2 cubic yards of soil removed per lawn was
 used; this resulted in disposal costs of $3,968 (Farrell, 1992). A sample calculation is shown below.
                                        ton
yd3 x 1.3 21 x $215 per ton = $3,968            Equation 4.8
                                        yd


       A typical transportation cost for hazardous waste is $425 per 22 ton dump truck for under 100
miles (Donegan, 1993). Assuming the truck is full and that the disposal site is within 100 miles the cost
is $425/22 tons equalling $19.32 per ton. This is $19.32 times 41  cubic yards times 1.3 tons per cubic
yard, equalling $1,040 for the high end cost. A sample calculation is shown below.


                         $19.31 per ton  x 14.2 yd3 x 1.3 —  * $360            Equation 4 9
                                                        yd3                    ^


       The low-end abatement is a resodding of the lawn.  The critical determinant of this cost is the
area resodded.  The high-end estimate was calculated  using the  average  size of lawn abated in the
Boston experience of the Urban Soil Lead Abatement Demonstration Project, equal to 2,141 square feet.
The average cost of resodding, including preparing the ground and applying the sod but not removing

   Abt Associates, Inc.                           4-12                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                                                      EXHIBIT 4-4
                                                         Summary of Abatement Costs for Lead in Sou*
Soil Abutment
Activity
Level
High


Activities
Removal of 6 inches of top (oil,
barrier installed and new soil
(tested at under 150 ppm) used as a
replacement, resodding plus high-
end dust abatement, plus hazardous
waste disposal of soil > 2000 ppm
plus the transportation costs for
disposing of hazardous soil.
Average of High and Low Costs
As above without the barrier and
using the Baltimore cost of
abatement plus dust abatement plus
10.9 cubic meters (14.2 cu.yd) soil
removed
Cost
Estimate
Level
High
Medium
Low

Costs
$ Value
>2000 ppm
Elements6: $9,600 + $750 +
$ll,460d + $1.040+ $10,000
(Only if exterior paint is
present)
Total: $22,850 + $10,000
(Only if exterior paint is
present)
>2000 ppm
Elements6: $7,248 + $750 +
Vl.l\4 + $700 + $5,000
(Only if exterior paint is
present)
Total: $16,412 + $5,000 (Only
if exterior paint is present)
> 2000 ppm
Elements*: $4,896 + $750 +
$3,968d + $360 + $3,000
(Only if exterior paint is
present)
Total: $9,974 + $3,000 (Only
if exterior paint is present)
£2000 ppm
Elements6: $9.600 + $750 +
$10,000 (Only if exterior paint is
present)
Total: $10,350 + $10,000 (Only
if exterior paint is present)
£2000 ppm
Elements': $7,248 + $750 +
$5.000 (Only if exterior paint is
present)
Total: $7,998 + $5,000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)
£2000 ppm
Elements11: $4,896 + $750 +
$3,000 (Only if exterior paint is
present)
Total: $5,646 + $3.000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)
Source
Weitzman, 1992 for soil
abatement protocol, Elias,
1993 for soil abatement
cost and Donegan, 1993
for hazardous waste
costs and Michigan, 1991
for exterior lead-paint
abatement
Avenge of high and low
values for soil abatement
and Michigan, 1991 for
exterior paint abatement
costs
EPA, 1993 for amount of
soil and Elias, 1993 for
cost of soil abatement and
Donegan, 1993 for cost of
disposal and transport of
hazardous waste and
Michigan, 1991 for
exterior paint abatement
costs
Effectiveness

Soil is abated
to 100 ppm

Duration
Pornuiiwnt

Abt Associates, Inc.
4-13
                                                                                     Draft. January 10, 1994

-------
                                                                                EXHIBIT 4-4
                                                                Summary of Abatement Costs for Lead in Soil*
SoQAbal
Activity
I JMMj
Level
Low


count
Activities

Resodding 2.141 iquara feet ®
$1 .4S/square foot plus mean high-
end dud abatement
Activities include resodding a little
grading but no removal of existing
grass
Avenge of high and low
Resodding 770 square feet 9
$1 .45/squire foot plus mean high-
end dust abatement (10.9 cu.m. per
property x 3S.3 cu ft/cu.m at 6")

Cost
Estimate
Level
High
Medium
Low

Costs
$ Value
Elements': $3,104 + $750
Total: $3,854
Elements': $2,1 10+ $750
Total: $2,860
Elements*: $1,116 + $750
Total: $1,866


Source
Weitzman, 1992 for size of
lawn and Degen, 1993 for
cost of resodding
Average of high and low
EPA, 1993 Baltimore
experience for size of lawn
and Degen, 1993 for cost
of resodding

Effectiveness

Soil is abated
toSOOppm



Duration

5 years


* $9.600 = High-cost/High-end soil; $750 = Avenge-cosl/High-end dust; $11.460 = High-cost soil disposal; $1,040 = High-cost transport; $10,000 = High-cost exterior lead paint abatement
« $9.600 = High-cost/High-end soil; $750 = Average-cost/High-enddust; $10,000 = High-cost exterior lead paint abatement.
« Assumes removal of 6 inches and is the difference of hazardous waste dispossl and regular landfilling since the Urban Soil Lead Abatement Demonstration Project values include soil disposal
  $7,248 = Medium-cost/High-endsoil; $750 = Average-cost/High-enddust; $7,714 = Medium-cost soil disposal; $700 = Medium-cost transport;
     $5,000 = Medium-cost exterior lead paint abatement.
f $7,248 = Medium-cost/High-endsoil; $750 = Average-cost/High-enddust; $5,000 = Medium-cost exterior lead paint abatement.
* $4,896 = Low-cost/High-end soil; $750 = Average-cost/High-end dust; $3,968 = Low-cost soil disposal; $360 = Low-cost transport; $3,000 = Low-cost exterior lead paint abatement
? $4,896 = Low-cost/High-end soil; $750 = Average-cost/High-end dust; $3.000 = Low-cost exterior lead paint abatement.
I $3.104 = High-cost/Low-endsoil lead abatement; $750 = Average-cost/High-enddust abatement.
J $2.110 = Medium-cost/Low-end soil lead abatement; $750 Average-cost/High-enddust abatement.
k $1,116 = Low-cost/Low-end soil lead abatement; $750 = Average-cost/High-enddust abatement.
Abt Associates, Inc.
4-14
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
  existing sod, is about $1.45 per square foot based on informal interviews with landscapes.  The
 total high cost is thus $3,104. The low estimate of $1,116 is calculated using the same cost per
 square foot applied to the average size of the lawn abated in Baltimore (770 square feet); this
 area was calculated based on the amount of soil removed.  The medium estimate is the mean of
 the high and low estimates. Including dust abatement, the totals are $3,854, $2,860, and $1,866
 as shown in Exhibit 4-4.  The high cost estimate is shown below as a sample calculation.


                            $1.45 x 2,141 ft1 + $750 = $3,854            Equation 4.10

 These estimates may be low compared to resodding an entire suburban lawn of 2,500 to 7,000
 square feet (a typical size range) but may represent a realistic value if only a portion of the lawn
 is resodded.  In  addition, the cost of resodding can vary based on  the physical layout  of the
 property. For example, if trees are present, additional labor will be required to sod around such
 obstacles raising the $1.45 per square foot estimate.

       Effectiveness.  The high end abatement is assumed to reduce the soil lead level to  100
 ppm, the average of the lead levels in the replacement soil in the Urban Soil Lead Abatement
 Demonstration Project (US EPA, 1993). The low-end estimate for the effectiveness of resodding
 is 500 ppm since in the past, the Agency has used this value  as an  action  level.   No
 measurements of the effectiveness of resodding were found.

    Duration. The high-end soil abatement is permanent as long as there are no external sources
 of  lead.   The  low-end abatement (resodding)  was assumed  to last five years based on
 expectations of sod durability obtained from landscaping firms in an informal survey.

    Effect of Bare Soil on Soil Abatement  Cost Scenarios.   The cost of the high-end soil
 abatement scenario may be slightly higher for covered soil than  for bare soil if extra sod must
 be removed from the yard;   the low-end soil abatement may not be needed at all if the sod
 covering the soil is intact.  The effectiveness of the two abatement scenarios  as measured by the
 post-abatement soil lead level is unaffected by the initial condition although resodding would  not
 achieve significant reduction in exposure if the soil were already covered. Initial soil coverage
 conditions would have no affect on the abatement duration.  As mentioned in Chapter 3, data
 limitations make us unable to specifically address bare and covered soils. Qualitative  discussions
 of the implications of this limiation for the benefit and benefit-cost results are contained in
 Chapters 5 and 7.


 4.2.4. Combined Abatement Scenario Costs

   Exhibits 4-1 through 4-4 showed the costs of abatements in each medium. These  abatements
 were combined into ten plausible scenarios that are summarized in Exhibits 4-5 and  4-7 below.
 In practice there will be considerable variation in the costs.  A  formal survey of current lead
 abatement practice could provide better estimates of the true costs; in addition, a controlled study
 could provide better data on the effectiveness and duration of the abatement techniques.  In
 further work, a sensitivity analysis is planned to address the uncertainty in these estimates. The
 exhibits show the ten abatement strategies analyzed in this report (the eleventh "no abatement"

Abt Associates. Inc.                          4-15                       Draft. January 10. 1994

-------
 has no cost) and the lifetime cost of the strategy in the year of abatement.  A seven percent
 discount factor was used to calculate the net present values.  The values are presented in
 Exhibits 4-5 and 4-6.  The calculation of abatement costs that occur over the homes' lifetime,
 low-end soil and recurrent dust, were further discounted by 0.5% per year to account for the
 removal of homes from the housing stock.

    Because damages to children occur only through age seven in the main model analysis,
 abatement should only occur when a child under the age of seven is resident in the home.  The
 values used here include all years, once an abatement is undertaken.  This provides an accurate
 estimate for those abatements that are permanent  but it overestimates the cost of recurrent
 abatements because the abatement activity, such as  resodding, should only occur when a child
 under seven is resident.

 4.2.5 Enforcement Costs

    There are no enforcement costs associated with  Section 403.  Section 403 requires that the
 Agency set hazard levels for lead in paint, soil and dust that will be used in other sections of
 Title X to trigger abatements.  The  enforcement  costs of these actions,  however, are  not
 attributable to Section 403 but to the section of the rule requiring the abatement.  All abatement
 activity under Section 403 is voluntary and thus incurs no enforcement cost.

 4.2.6 Implementation Costs

    The implementation costs associated with Section 403 are of two types. The first is the cost
 of setting and promulgating the Section 403 hazard levels themselves; a negligible cost compared
 to the funding appropriated in  Tide  X  for abatement ($250 million in 1994).  The second
 implementation costs would be those of states or localities that voluntarily use the hazard  levels
 set by the Agency as action levels in their own lead management programs.  The size of these
 costs depend on the current level of activity at the state and local level, whether the hazard levels
 the Agency sets are above or below those of the programs in place, and the number of programs
 that implement the hazard levels. If the Agency levels are more stringent than current practice,
 implementation costs could be significant; however  if the Agency  levels are higher than those
 in practice implementation costs  will  be  negligible.   No quantitative  evaluation of  the
 implementation costs was attempted because reliable  information on current and expected future
 programs at the state and local level was not available.  If implementation costs are proportional
 to the number of homes affected, which could be the case if state or local authorities decided
 to track homes to assure abatement, then the inclusion of implementation costs in the benefit-cost
 analysis would favor higher hazard levels over lower ones, all other things equal, since  the
 number of homes to be tracked would be lower under the latter than the former.
Abt Associates, Inc.                           4-16                      Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                              EXHIBIT 4-5

                               Summary of Unit Abatement Costs by Scenario
  Single Media Abatement
  Scenarios
                            Activities
Unit Cost
  High-end Paint Abatement
                            Paint abatement and dust
                            abatement
High Estimate - $12,750
Medium Estimate- $10,500
Low Estimate- $8,250
  Low-end Paint Abatement
                            Window abatement and
                            dust abatement
High Estimate - $3,750
Medium Estimate- $2,750
Low Estimate - $1,750
  Non-Recurrent Dust
                           One high-end dust
                           abatement
High Estimate - $1200
Medium Estimate - $750
Low Estimate - $300
  Recurrent Dust
                           High-end dust every 10
                           years, Low-end dust
                           monthly
Ten year   Monthly   Total Cost Estimate3
                                                           High
                                                           High
                                                           Low
                                                           Low
                                                           Medium
                                                           Medium
                                                                High
                                                                Low
                                                                High
                                                                Low
                                                                High
                                                                Low
                      $14,621
                       $8,524
                      $12,925
                       $6,828
                      $13,773
                       $7,676
  High-end Soil Abatement
                           Complete removal and
                           replacement of soil
                           (includes disposal and
                           transportation of
                           hazardous waste for
                           concentrations above 2000
                           ppm and also exterior
                           paint abatement with
                           additional cost for those
                           houses with exterior paint)
High cost
                                                           >2000 ppm and exterior paint - $32,850
                                                           £2000 ppm and exterior paint - $20,350
                                                           >2000 ppm and no exterior paint - $22,850
                                                           £2000 ppm and no exterior paint - $10,350

                                                           Medium cost
                                                           >2000 ppm and exterior paint - $21,412
                                                           £2000 ppm and exterior paint - $12,998
                                                           >2000 ppm and no exterior paint - $16,412
                                                           £2000 ppm and no exterior paint - $7,998

                                                           Low cost
                                                           >2000 ppm and exterior paint - $12,974
                                                           £2000 ppm and exterior paint - $8,646
                                                           >2000 ppm and no exterior paint - $9,974
                                                           £2000 ppm and no exterior paint - $5,646
  Low-end Soil Abatement
                           Resod every 5 years,
                           High-end dust abatement
                           at first resodding
High3 - $10,669
Medium3 - $7,493
Low1 -  $4,316
rate.
 Includes discounting at 7%  to the year of abatement and removal of housing stock at a 0.5%
(Total cost would be further discounted to 1994.)

-------
                                                                                          EXHIBIT 4-6

                                                                           Summary of Combined Abatement Strategies
Net Present Value Costs for Combined Scenarios
Scenario
High-end Paint and High-end Soil
High-end Paint and Low-end Soil

Cost Elements
>2000ppm
High*
$12.000 + $750 + $9,600 + $750 +
$11.460 + $1,040 + $10,000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)
Medium1*
$9,750 + $750 + $7,248 + $750 +
$700 + $7,714 + $5,000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)
Lowc
$7.500 + $750 + $4.896 + $750 +
$3,968 + $360 + $3.000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)
£2000 ppm
High
$12,000 + $750 + $9,600 +
$750+ $10,000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)
Medium
$9,750 + $750 + $7,248 +
$750 + $5,000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)
Low
$7,500 + $750 + $4,896 +
$750 + $3,000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)
Highd
$12,000 + $750 + $10,669
Medium6
$9,750 + $750 + $7,493
Low'
$7,500 + $750 + $4,316
Unit Costs - Discounted at 7 percent to the year of abatement
> 2000 ppm
High
$35,600 +$10,000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)
Medium
$26,912 +$5,000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)
Low
$18,224 + $3,000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)
High
$23,419

High
$23,100 +$10,000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)
Medium
$18,498 + $5,000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)
Low
$13,896 +$3,000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)

Medium
$17,993
Low
$12,566
• $12,000 = High-cost/High-end interior lead paint abatement; $750 = Average-cost/High-end dust abatement; $9,600 = High
-------
                                                                                           EXHIBIT 4-6

                                                                            Summary of Combined Abatement Strategies
Net Present Value Costs for Combined Scenarios
Low-end Paint and High-end Soil
Low-end Paint and Low-end Soil
>2000ppm
High*
$3.000 + $750 + $9.600 + $750 +
$11.460 + $1,040 + $10.000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)
Medium11
$2.000 + $750 + $7.248 + $750 +
$7.714 + $700 +$5,000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)
Low'
$1.000 + $750 + $4.896 + $750 +
$3,968 + $360 + $3,000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)

£2000 ppm
High
$3.000 + $750 + $9.600 +
$750+ $10,000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)
Medium
$2,000 + $750 + $7.248 +
$750+ $5,000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)
Low
$1,000 + 750 + $4.896 +
$750 + $3,000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)
High!
$3.000 + $750 + $10.669
Medium1
$2.000 + $750 + $7,493
Low1
$1,000 + $750 + $4.316

>2000 ppm
High
$26,600 + $10.000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)
Medium
$19. 162 +$5.000 (Only if
exterior paint ii present)
Low
$11, 724 + $3,000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)

£2000 ppm
High
$14, 100 +$10.000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)
Medium
$10.748 + $5,000 (Only if
exterior paint is present)
Low
$7,396 + $3,000 (Only if exterior
paint is present)
$14,419
$10,243
$6,066
8 $3,000 = High-cost/Low-end interior lead paint abatement; $750 = Average-cost/High-end dust abatement; $9,600 = High-cost/High-end soil lead abatement; $750 = Average-cost/High-end dust abatement;
          $11,460 = High-cost hazardous soil disposal; $1.040 = High-cost soil transport; $10,000 = High-cost exterior lead paint abatement.
  $2,000 = Medium-cost/Low-end interior lead paint abatement; $750 = Average-cost/High-end dust abatement; $7,248 = Medium-cost/High-end soil lead abatement;  $750 = Average-cost/High-end dust abatement;
          $7,714 = Medium-cost hazardous soil disposal; $700 =  Medium-cost soil transport; $5,000 = High-cost exterior lead paint abatement.
1 $1,000 = Low-cost/Low-end interior lead paint abatement; $750 = Average-cost/High-end dust abatement;  $4,896 = Low-cost/High-end soil lead abatement; $750 = Average-cost/High-end dust abatement;
          $3,968 = Low-cost hazardous soil disposal; $360 =  Low-cost soil transport; $3,000 = High-cost exterior lead paint abatement.
1 $3,000 = High-cost/Low-end interior lead paint abatement; $750 = Average-cost/High-end dust  abatement; $10,669 = High-cost/Low-end soil with resod every 5 yean and High-end dust abatement at first resodding
          (see Exhibit 4-5).
k $2,000 = Medium-cost/Low-end interior lead paint abatement; $750 = Average-cost/High-end dust abatement; $7,493  = Medium-cost/Low-end soil with resod every 5 years and High-end dust abatement at first resoddina
          (see Exhibit 4-5).
 $1,000 = Low-cost/Low-end interior lead paint abatement; $750 = Average-cost/High-end dust abatement; $4,316 = Low-cost/Low-end soil with resod every 5 years and High-end dust abatement at first resodding
          (see Exhibit 4-5).

-------
  4.3 SAMPLE COST CALCULATION

        A sample calculation is presented below for the total cost of each abatement scenario
  being analyzed. These equations build on those developed in Chapter 3 Section 1.4.

  The optimum net benefit model developed for Section 403 calculates total benefits and costs for
  a given set of assumptions regarding  anticipated lead abatement choices for a 50 year time
  period.6   Arriving at a present value estimate of costs or benefits  for a 50  year time frame
  requires the application of a multiplier to the base year's cost and benefits.
                                            **(*fybl99JF                    Equation 4. 1 1
 where:    C    = present value of total cost for 50 year period
           u     = unit cost of selected abatement for sample point y
           n     = number of sample points
           Ny    = number of homes (sample weight) for sample point y
           bim  = birth rate for base year (0.03994)
           F     = multiplying factor used to inflate cost to 50 years.

 If, in Equation 4-1 1, F were equal to 1 then C would equal the total cost for the base year.  F
 is a function of birth rate, housing removal and growth rate, and discount rate.  Because homes
 that contain lead paint are removed and replaced with homes that do not, the lead paint homes
 and non-lead paint homes have different growth rates and thus different inflation factors.

       The multipliers used here are just the multipliers for the first year, first births derived
 in Chapter 3 discounted to 1994 using a seven percent rate. For  lead-paint-based homes this
 value is 8.79; the derivation is shown in Exhibit 4-7.  For lead-paint-free homes the multiplier
 is larger (12.48) because the population grows each year. (See Exhibit 4-8 for the calculation.)

       Note that  Equation 4.1 1 is also used to calculate the costs of lead testing.  In this case,
 the unit cost u is  the cost of testing and depends on the number of media tested. For example',
 if interior paint and dust are both tested, then the unit testing cost  is $460.  If all three media
 (interior paint, dust and soil) are tested, the unit cost is $598. Exterior paint testing is done only
 when high-end soil abatement is  chosen and adds another $115 to the total unit testing costs.
       Fifty years was chosen as the modelling period because the net present value of the benefits accruing to
children born in the fiftieth year are less than one percent of the dollar value in year fifty using a seven percent
discount rate. Note benefits do not begin to accrue until age 18.

Abt Associates. Inc.                           4-20                       Draft. January 10. 1994

-------
EXHIBIT 4-7
Calculation of Lead Paint House Cost Mnltinfier
Year©

1995(1)



1999(5)
























2024(30)
2025(31)

2027(33)
2028(34)

2030(36)

2032(38)
2033(39)
2034(40)
2035(41)


2038(44)

2040(46)

2042(48)

Amnd Cffmpomats of Abatement
Dedsraus Made -

0.9385
0.8835
0.8298
0.7797
0.7349
0.6910
0.6629
0.6341
0.6066
0.5804
0.5554
0.5330
0.5101
0.4882
0.4673
0.4486
0.4294
0.4111
0.3936
0.3768

0.3456
0.3310
0.3171
0.3038
0.2910
0.2788
0.2664
0.2553
0.2440
0.2340
0.2236
0.2145

0.1967
0.1887
0.1816
0.1748

0.1619
0.1558


0.1388
0.1336
0.1286
0.1237
0.1191

(Interest Rate)1

1.0700
1.1449
1,2250
1.3108
1.4026

1.6058
1.7182
1.8385
1.9672
2.1049
2.2522
2.4098
2.5785
2.7590
2.9522
3.1588
3.3799
3.6165
3.8697
4.1406
4.4304
4.7405
5.0724
5.4274
5.8074
6.2139
6.6488
7.1143
7.6123
8.1451
8.7153
9.3253
9.9781
10.6766
11.4239
12.2236
13.0793
13.9948
14.9745
16.0227
17.1443
18.3444
19.6285
21.0025
22.4726

25.7289
27.5299
Abatement Cost Lead Homes Multiplier
>M 	 !
-------
                                              EXHIBIT 4J8
                                    Calculation of Non-Lead
                                                             Hones Multiplier
1 ' .

1





7

9
10
11

13
14
IS

17
18
19
20

22
23

25
26
27

29
30
31

33
34
35


38
39
40

42
43.

45
46
47

49
Year
1994
1995


1998

2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008

2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
2019
2020
2021
2022
2023

2025
2026
2027
2028
2029
2030
2031
2032
2033
2034
2035
2036
2037
2038
2039
2040
2041
2042
2043
Births
1.885
1.832
1.782

1,693
1.653
1.616
1499
1,584
1.S69
1,555
1,542
1.530
1,519
1,508
1.498
1.488
1.483
1.478
1,473
1,469
1.465
1.462
1.459
1,456
1.454
1.452
1.440
1,429
1,418
1.408


1.382
1.374
1,367
1.361
1.357
1.354
1.351
1.348
1.346
1.343
1,341
1,340
1.338
1.337
1.331
1.327
1,322
(Interest Rate)1
1.00
1.07
1.14
1.23
131
1.40
1.50
1.61
1.72
1.84
1.97
2.10
2.25
2.41
2.58
2.76
2.95
3.16
3.38
3.62
3.87
4.14
4.43
4.74
5.07
5.43
5.81
6.21
6.65
7.11
7.61
8.15
8.72
9.33
9.98
10.68
11.42
12.22
13.08
13.99
14.97
16.02
17.14
18.34
19.63
21.00
22.47
24.05
25.73
27.53
Total Discounted Births
Multiplier (Tout Discounted Births/First Year Births)
Discounted Births II
1885.40
1712.04
1556.64
1417.12
1291.64
1178.61
1076.64
995.93
921.73
853.47
790.63
732.75
679.40
630.20
584.81
542.90
504.19
469.45
437.24
407.36
379.63
353.89
329.98
307.76
287.10
267.90
250.03
231.74
214.89
199.34
184.99
171.75
159.51
148.20
137.74
128.05
119.09
111.02
103.51
96.53
90.03
83.99
78.36
73.12
68.25
63.71
59.47
55.37
51.57
48.03
23522.69
12.48
Abt Associates, Inc.
4-22
                                                                                      Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 4.4    RESULTS

        A typical regulatory impact analysis will evaluate the costs of various regulatory
 alternatives.  The objective of this Section 403 analysis is to choose alternative hazard levels for
 lead in paint, soil and dust. As a method of investigating the impacts of various levels of lead
 on abatement, the net benefits are used as a tool to identify possible regulatory hazard levels.
 The consequence of using net benefits as the identifying criterion is that the costs presented in
 this section are intimately tied to the benefits analysis discussed in Chapter 5 and even more so
 to the benefit-cost results examined in Chapter 6. A brief discussion of the approaches used in
 the model is  contained in Chapter 3, and a thorough discussion in Chapter 6.

 4.4.1  Total Abatement Costs

        To serve as an appropriate guide for public policymaking, the cost estimates used in this
 analysis should be consistent with the concept of social costs. Because the data sources generally
 provided estimates of private  costs,  it is reasonable to determine whether there  are any
 divergences between these estimated costs and social costs. This evaluation must be conducted
 for each of the economic resources used in response to the promulgation of hazard levels under
 Section 403.  For the current discussion, these resources are classified generally as labor and
 capital and discussed in turn below.7

       The most common source of divergence between private and social costs of labor is
 associated with unemployment.  When unemployment exists, the costs of employing additional
 labor may be lower than the prevailing wage implies.  Consequently, if the regulation being
 considered here causes unemployed labor to be used,  the price of labor is  not accurately
 represented by the prevailing wage.  Gramlich proposes conditions to be met if unemployed
 labor is to be valued at less  than market rates in benefit-cost analyses (Gramlich, 1981). Given
 the fifty-year timeframe of this analysis, it is  unclear whether two  of these conditions can be
 met,  except intermittently, in the case of the hazard levels to be set under Section 403.  The first
 is that the reduction in  unemployment must be sustained, meaning that reduced unemployment
 today does not lead to inflation that generates more unemployment later.  The second condition
 is that the abatements  and other actions induced  by the promulgation hazard  levels do indeed
 lead to unemployment reductions that existing policies would not have addressed.  Abatements
 induced by this regulation will create additional demand for labor but it is unclear how much
 unemployed  labor  will be  provided to meet  this additional demand.   In part, making this
 determination is difficult since the size and composition of the pool of unemployed labor will
 fluctuate as the economy changes over the next 50 years.
       It is hard to summarize here the possible divergences between the social and private costs of a third class
of resources - the environment - since that in many ways is the focus of this analysis, as the discussion of market
failures in Chapter 3 indicated. Instead, any divergences between social and private costs of using the environment
are discussed as they arise throughout this report.  One example of such a divergence comes in the form of the
positive externality to future residents from the abatement of a given home, which is modelled in the benefit
estimation.


Abr Associates. Inc.                           4-23                       Draft. January 10. 1994

-------
        Without an indication that the social costs of labor will be less than the private costs
 during the time period of this analysis, it was assumed that private labor costs adequately reflect
 social costs. This position is bolstered by the likelihood that the estimates of private costs used
 in this analysis may be too low during periods of high demand for the type of labor used in
 abatement. In short, there are downward and upward tendencies to the labor estimates used here
 from the social costs of labor they are meant to represent. These tendencies imply that any point
 estimate of labor costs may have a great deal of variance associated  with it.  However,  the
 direction of any net biases are unknown.

        With regard to capital, one of the most common forms of divergence between social and
 private costs hinges on whether investment is displaced by the lead abatements and other actions
 induced by this rule. The opportunity cost of displaced investment is the present value of the
 consumption stream that could be generated by that investment. This concept is also known as
 the shadow price of capital.  At one extreme, if investment is completely displaced, capital costs
 should be multiplied by the shadow price of capital, which is estimated to be approximately 2.5,
 in order to express the  capital costs in terms of consumption,  and then discounted back to  the
 present using the social rate of time preference (Scheraga,  1989).  At the other extreme, if no
 investment is to be displaced, abatement costs must be funded entirely from current consumption
 (implying a  shadow price of capital equal to one).  An assumption  of no displacement of
 investment  was applied in the  main analysis.   An alternative approach which allows  for
 displacing investment over varying timeframes is considered in sensitivity analyses in Chapter
 7. These analyses are based upon a two-stage discounting procedure.

       The total cost of any of the decision rules is the sum of the testing and abatement costs.
 These, in turn, are a function of the number of homes undergoing testing and abatement and the
 type of testing or abatement being done.  Exhibit 4-9 shows the costs by abatement type for each
 of the five decision rules used in this analysis.  (See Chapter 3 Section 3.4 for a discussion of
 the decision rules.)   Exhibit 4-10 shows  the number of homes abated by type of abatement for
 each rule.  The results discussed here were calculated using the medium value of the abatement
 costs discounted at seven percent as shown in Exhibits 4-5 and 4-6. Results for high and low
 abatement costs as well as costs calculated using the two-stage discounting procedure will be
 discussed as part of the  sensitivity analyses in Chapter 7.

       The total testing costs for each decision rule are shown in Exhibit 4-9.  For the four
 decision rules that did not have an explicit dust condition or did not permit non-recurrent dust
 abatement as an option, only  interior paint (in pre-1980  homes) and soil were tested.  The
 resulting total testing costs were $14,982 million.  For the remainder of the decision rules, all
 three media were tested. In the voluntary optimum case, no exterior paint testing was required
 because the high-end soil abatement was never chosen.  The total testing costs were $24,222
 million.  In the remaining four decision rules, exterior paint testing costs were added for a total
 of $24,346 million.   The testing costs and abatement costs are  summed to yield the total costs
 discussed below.
Abl Associates. Inc.                           4-24                       Draft, January 10. 1994

-------
                                                                                    EXHIBIT 4-9

                                                           Total Costs for  Five Alternative Decision Rules

'•
2.
3.
4.
5.
Decision Rule.8
Voluntary
Optimum''
Paint Condition
Only6
Single
Medium
Plus
Condition*1
2-Media
Plui
Condition6
3a.
3b.
3c.
4a.
4b.
4c.
3-Media Pliu
Conditionf
Soil
(ppm)
-
-
2.300
•
-
2.300
2.300
-
2.300
Dint
(ppm)
-
-
-
1.200
-
1.200
-
1.200
1.200
Paint
(XRF.
mi/em')
-
•
-
-
20
-
20
20
20
Noninlact Paint
Abtttcmcnt
Recommended
No
Ye.
Ye.
Ye.
Ye.
Ye.
Ye.
Ye.
Ye.
Abatement
Coiti
(S million)
13.896
24.66S
28.344
29.646
25.013
31.903
28.689
29.991
32,248
Testing Costs
(S million)
24.222
14.982
14.982
24.346
14.982
24.346
14.982
24.346
24.346
Total Costs
($ million)
38.118
39.630
43.326
53.992
39.995
56.249
43.671
54.337
56.594
Costs by Type of Abatement Chosen1 ($ million)
HP

20.134
20.134
20.260
20.429
20.260
20.429
20.555
20.555
LP
26
3.517
3.442
3.462
3.567
3.387
3.493
3.551
3.438
HS



272

272

272
272
IS
1.992

3.475
1.420

3.475
3.475
1.420
3.475
RD



978

978

978
978
HP/HS









HP/LS

943
943
943
943
943
943
943
943
LP/HS



87

87

87
87
LP/LS

74
350
74
74
350
350
74
350
NRD
11.878


2.150

2.150

2.150
2.150
                                                                                                                                               choose the paint abatement method that generates (he
•Candidate hazard levels examined ranged up to 3000 ppm for soil. 2000 ppm for dust and 20 mg/cm'
•Each home selects abatement (or no abatement) that has highest net benefit.
'Abatement a recommended for homes with more than five square feet of lead -based paint in nonintact condition, regardless of XRF level or net benefits. Home
highest net benefits. Results are reported only for homes that exceed recommended levels.
dWithin the Aill range of individual soil, dust and paint hazard levels that could be set as a threshold for action, with no constraints placed onl eh other two media, the levels specified in the table maximize the net benefits  Results
are reported only for homes that exceed recommended levels.
•Within the full range of individual soil, dust and paint hazard level combination that could be set as a threshold for action, with no restriction on the other medium, the levels specified in the table maximize the net benefits
Results are reported only for homes that exceed recommended levels.
'Within the fall range of individual soil, dust and paint hazard level combination that could be set as a threshold for action, with no restriction on the other medium, the levels specified in the table maximize the net benefits
Results are reported only for homes that exceed recommended leveb.
tAbalement Codes: High PabiKHP): Low PainKLP): High Soil(HS); Low Soil(LS); Recurrent Dust (RD): High Paint and High Soil(HP/HS); High Paint and Low Soil(HP/LS); Low Paint and High Soil (LP/HS)- Low Paint
and Low Soil (LP/LS): Nonrecurrent Dust (NRD). The abatement activities were described in Exhibits 4.1-4.6.
Abt Associates, Inc.
                                                                4-25
Draft, January 10,  1994

-------
                                                                                           EXHIBIT 4-10

                                                                  Distribution of Abatement Chokw for Five Alternative Decision Rube

1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
Deciiion Rules*
Voluntary
Optimum''
Punt Condition
Onlyc
Single
Medium
Phis
Condition"1
2-Media
Plus
Condition*
3*.
3b.
3c.
4a.
4b.
4c.
3-Media Plus
Condition'
Soil
(ppm)
-
-
2.300
-
-
2.300
2.300
-
2.300
Dust
(ppm)
-
-
-
1.200
-
1.200
-
1.200
1.200
Paint
(XRF.
mg/cirf)
-
-
-
-
20
-
20
20
20
Noninlacl
Paint
Abatement
Recommended
No
Yea
Yes
Yea
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Total
Number of
Abatements
(Thousands)
45.165
7,064
S.070
15.603
7,164
16.197
8.169
15.702
16.297

HP

4.160
4.160
4.186
4.220
4.186
4.220
4.246
4.246

LP
21
2.774
2.716
2.731
2.814
2.672
2.755
2.770
2.712

HS



74

74

74
74
Number of Abatements by Type Chosen1
(Thousand.)
IS
577

1.006
411

1.006
1.006
411
1.006
RD



276

276

276
276
HP/HS









HP/LS

114
114
114
114
114
114
114
114
LP/HS



18

18

18
18
LP/LS

16
74
16
16
74
74
16
74
NRD
44.567


7.777

7.777

7.777
7.777
                                                                                                                                                                                 Dd thai generate* me
*Candidate hazard levels examined ranged up to 3000 ppm for soil. 2000 ppm for dust and 20 mg/cm*
bEach home selects abatement (or no abatement) that has highest net benefits
'Abatement is recommended for homes with more than five square feet of lead -based paint in nonintact condition, regardless of XRF level or net benefits.  Home owners choose the punt abatement
highest net benefits. Results are reported only for homes that exceed recommended levels.
'Within the full range of individual soil, dust and paint hazard levels that could be set as a threshold for action, with no constraints placed onl eh other two media, the levels specified in the table maximize the net benefits. Results
are reported only for homes that exceed recommended levels.
eWhhin the full range of individual soil, dust and paint hazard level combination that could be set as a threshold for action, with no restriction on the other medium, the levels specified in the table maximize the net benefits.
Results are reported only for homes that exceed  recommended levels.
'Within the full range of individual soil, dust and paint hazard level combination that could be set as a threshold for action, with no restriction on the other medium, the levels specified hi the table maximize the net benefits.
Results ire reported only for homes that exceed  recommended levels.
(Abatement Codes: High Paint(HP); Low PanutLP); High Soil(HS); Low SoiKLS); Recurrent Dust (RD); High Paint and High Soil(HP/HS); High Paint and Low Soil(HP/LS); Low Paint and High Soil (LP/HS); Low Paint
and Low Soil (LP/LS); Nonrecurrent Dust (NRD).  The abatement activities were described in Exhibits 4.1-4.6. discussed below.
Abt Associates, Inc.
                                                                   4-26
Draft, January  10, 1994

-------
       The voluntary optimum decision rule has the lowest total costs of any of the  rules
 considered ($38,118 million) and the largest number of abatements recommended, just over 45
 million.  The overwhelming majority of the abatements were non-recurrent dust, the lowest unit
 cost abatement.  Once constraining conditions are added to the decision rules, the total costs rise,
 not because the number of abatements increases (in fact they decrease), but because the  types
 of abatements necessary to meet the decision rule requirements have higher unit costs.

       The remaining eight decision rules all recommend nonintact paint abatement as either part
 or all of the abatement. One of these decision rules recommends only nonintact paint be abated;
 in this case, 7 million  abatements are performed at a total testing and abatement cost of $40
 billion.  While fewer abatements are performed  under this rule than  under the voluntary
 optimum, they are paint abatements (alone or in combination with soil abatements), that have
 higher unit  costs than non-recurrent dust abatement, the voluntary optimum preferred choice.
 The lower testing costs under this decision rule result from testing only paint and soil. Because
 dust abatement will not satisfy the constraining condition (that paint in bad condition be abated),
 there is no need for dust testing.

       The next seven constrained decision rules each have higher costs and a larger number of
 abatements.  The non-intact paint abatement condition, with a cost of $24.6 billion, represents
 the majority of the abatement cost in all the remaining rules. The single media constrained cases
 add to this base.  A soil condition at 2,300 ppm adds about $3.7 billion to the paint condition
 base cost, the 1,200 ppm dust condition adds both soil and dust abatements totaling $5 billion.
 An intact paint XRF condition of 20 mg/cm2 adds less than half a billion dollars to the nonintact
 paint abatement cost.  The three two-media constrained decision rules also add costs to the  paint
 condition  base.  With  a decision rule  of abating  soil to 2,300 ppm and dust to 1,200, the
 additional cost is about $7 billion.  Adding soil at 2,300 ppm and paint at 20 mg/cm2 adds only
 $4 billion while adding dust (1,200 ppm) and paint (20 mg/cm2) conditions adds $5.3 billion.
 Finally, the three media constrained case adds $7.6 billion to the paint condition base making
 it the most costly option considered.  Chapter 6 will compare the costs incurred to the monetized
 benefits discussed in Chapter 5.

 4.4.2  Quantity of Hazardous Waste Generated by Abatement

       The amount of hazardous waste that will be generated under each decision rule, based
 on the Resource Conservation and  Recovery Act  (RCRA) disposability requirements, is an
 additional consideration when evaluating the  hazard  level choices.  The applicability of the
 RCRA standards and the potential quantity of waste generated is  described below for  each
 medium.  As was discussed in Section 4.2.2, the Agency has yet ruled on whether residential
 lead abatement wastes will be considered hazardous waste. It is also possible that the hazardous
 wastes generated will be treated, and disposed of as  non-hazardous waste, in which case the
 hazardous waste capacity would not  be an issue.
Abt Associates, Inc.                           4-27                       Draft. January 10, 1994

-------
 Paint
        In the Housing and Uiban Development abatement demonstration project, an average of
 217 pounds of hazardous waste was generated per housing unit in the three cities for which data
 was available (US EPA, 1992a). This estimate does not include all the laige solid debris which
 was not considered hazardous.   The method of abatement used may affect the amount of
 hazardous waste generated, however, chemical stripping and abrasive removal, methods more
 likely to create hazardous waste,  were not considered in our model, nor are they likely to be
 widely used. Because the disposal cost is a small percentage of the overall paint abatement cost
 no explicit consideration of hazardous waste disposal was included in the modelled abatement
 cost.  A second consideration however,  is the total quantity of waste that would be generated
 under each of the proposed decision rules.  Exhibit 4-11 shows the total and annualized volume
 of hazardous waste from paint abatement.  These values are compared to the total quantity of
 hazardous waste, 197,501,112 tons, generated in the United States in 1989 (US EPA, 1992b).
 As Exhibit 4-11 shows, the hazardous waste generated by lead-based paint abatement is less than
 a tenth of a percent of the total national  annual hazardous waste generation.
 Dust

       Dust abatement is expected to generate a very small quantity (< 20 pounds/unit) of waste
 that could be considered hazardous. This was assumed to be excluded from RCRA regulation
 under the household waste exemption criterion  (Fortuna,  1987).

 SoU

       The hazardous waste from soil was explicitly considered in the cost of soil abatement
 when the soil was abated by  removal.  The medium cost estimate presented in this report
 assumed removal of 35.9 tons of soil per unit. Using this value and the number of high-end soil
 abatements as reported by decision rule in Exhibit 4-10, the total quantity of hazardous soil
 generated was calculated for each decision rule. The results are shown in Exhibit 4-11.  The
 total annual contribution of soil abatement is less than one tenth of one percent of the total
 hazardous waste generated annually.  Based on these results the quantity of hazardous waste
 generated is not a  significant concern although  the cost contribution of disposing of the waste
 could be significant.
Abt Associates, Inc.                           4-28                      Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                                                                 EXHIBIT 4-11

                             Volume of Hazardous  Waste Generated by Media for Five Alternative Decision Rules

1.
2.
3.
4.
S.
Dccuion Rules*
Voluntary
Optimum
Paint Condition
Only'
Single
Medium
Plus
Condition
2-Medh
Plus
Condition"
3a.
3b.
3c.
4a.
4b
4c.
3-Media Phu
Condition^
Soil
(ppm)
-

2.300
•

2.300
2.300
-
2.300
Dust
(ppm)
-
-
-
1.200
•
1.200
-
1.200
1.200
hint
(XRF.
mg/cm1)
-
•
•
-
20

20
20
20
Nonintict
Flint
Abatement
Recommend oo
No
Yes
Y«
Yes
Yes
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Total Volume of
Hazaidoua Waste
Ocneraled Over Fifty
Yean
(Thousand Tom)
2
696
696
3.998
705
3.998
70S
4.008
4.008
Volume of Hazardous
Wute Generated Over
Fifty Yean by Media
and Decision Rule*
(Thousand Tons)
Paint
2
696
o9o
696
70S
696
70S
70S
70S
Soil
0
0
0
3.303
0
3.303
0
3.303
3.303
Volume of Hazardous
Waste Generated Annually
by Media and Decision
Rule
(Thousand Tons)
Paint
.04
14
14
14
14
14
14
14
14
Soil
0
0
0
66
0
66
0
66
66
Lead Abatement
Hazardous Waste aa
Percent of Total
Hazardous Waste
Generated Annually
•e.OOOl*
.007%
.007*
.04*
.007*
.04%
.007%
.04%
.04%
                                                                                                                                                 e owner* choose the paint abatement method
^Candidate hazard leveb examined ranged up to 3000 ppm Tor soil. 2000 ppm for dust and 20 mg/cm'
"•Each home select! abatement (or no abatement) that has highest net benefits
'Abatement b recommended for homes with more than five square feet of lead -based paint in nonintact condition, regardless of XRF level or net benefits. He
that generates the highest net benefits. Results are reported only for homes that exceed recommended leveb.
'Within the hill range of individual soil, dust and paint hazard leveb that could be set as a threshold for action, with no constraints placed ont eh other two media, die leveb specified bi die table maximize
the net benefits. Results an reported only for homes that exceed recommended leveb
'Within the full range of individual soil, dust and paint hazard level combination that could be set as a threshold for action, with no restriction on the other medium, the levels specified in the table maximize
the net benefits. Results are reported only for homes that exceed recommended leveb.
'Within the hill range of individual soil, dust and paint hazard level combination that could be set as a threshold for action, with no restriction on the other medium, the leveb specified in die table maximize
the net benefits. Results are reported only for homes that exceed recommended leveb.
Abt Associates, Inc.
                                               4-29
Draft, January 10,  1994

-------
4.5   REFERENCES

Carroll, M. 1993. Lead-paint Battle May Get Less Costly.  The Boston Globe, January 30.

Clark, S., R. Bomschein, P. Succop, S. Roda, and B. Peace.  1991. Urban Lead Exposures
      of Children in Cincinnati, Ohio. Chemical Speciation and Bioavailability.  3(3): 163-
      171.

Degen, J. 1993.  Personal Communication with Joshua Degen, Earthscape, Inc., Brighton,
      MA, June, 1993.

Donegan, T. 1993. Personal Communication with Thomas Donegan, Chemical Waste
      Management, Oak Brook, IL. July.

Elias, R. 1993.  Personal Communication with Rob Elias, U.S. Environmental Protection
      Agency.  March 16.

Farrell, K., et al.  1992. Baltimore Soil Lead Abatement Demonstration Project.  Final
      Report. July 31.

Fortuna,  R. et al.  1987. Hazardous Waste Regulation the New Era.  McGraw-Hill, Inc.

Gramlich, E. M.  1981. Benefit-Cost Analysis of Government Programs. Prentice-Hall, Inc.,
      Englewood Cliffs, NJ, p. 67.

Michigan Department of Public Health (Michigan). 1991. Recommended Abatement
      Procedures and Cost Estimate Data. December, 1991.

R. S. Means Company, Inc.  1988.  Means Residential Cost Data 1988. Construction
      Consultants and Publishers, Kingston, MA.

Morris, V. 1993.  Personal Communication with Vance Morris, Maryland Department of
      Housing and Community Development, Annapolis, MD.

Rohmer,  R.  1993. Personal Communication with Rosemary Rohmer, Maid in the USA,
      Boston, MA.

Scheraga, J. 1989.  Supplemental Guidelines on Discounting in the Preparation of
      Regulatory Impact Analyses.  Economic Studies Branch, Office of Policy,
      Planning and Evaluation, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Washington,
      DC, March.

Ullucci, P. 1993.  Personal Communication with Paul A. Ulluci, Technical Director, ESA
      Laboratories,  Bedford, MA.

U.S. Department of Health and Human Services  Public Health Services Centers for Disease


Abt Associates, Inc.                          4-30                     Draft, January 10,  1994

-------
       Control (CDC). 1991. Strategic Plan for the Elimination of Childhood Lead
       Poisoning. February.

 U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD). 1990.  Comprehensive and
       Workable Plan for the Abatement of Lead-Based Paint in Privately Owned Housing:
       Report to Congress.  Washington, DC. December.

 U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 1992.(US EPA, 1992a)  "Applicability of RCRA
       Disposal Requirements to Lead-based Paint Abatement Wastes", Office of Pollution
       Prevention and Toxics, June.

 U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 1992. (US EPA, 19925) "1989 National Biennial
       Report of Hazardous Waste Generators and Treatment, Storage, and Disposal
       Facilities Requested Under RCRA.  Office of Solid Waste.

 U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA).   1993.  Urban Soil Lead Abatement
       Demonstration Project - Integrated Report. April IS. Draft.

 Weitzman, M., et al.  1992.  Boston lead-in-soil/lead free kids demonstration project.  Final
       Report.
Abt Associates, Inc.                         4-31                      Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                     5. BENEFITS
5.1    GENERAL ASSUMPTIONS

       Chapter 3 provided a description of the methodology used to produce the "baseline"
hazard assessment  of children's  exposure to lead  from paint, soil  and dust in US private
housing stock.  A basic premise of the baseline hazard assessment is that in the absence of
establishing Section 403  hazard  levels to induce property owners  to  perform abatements,
children born each year over the next several decades will experience exposure to lead from
paint, soil and dust in patterns that are, for the most part, similar to current exposure patterns.
As a result, they will also incur the health damages associated with those patterns of exposure.

       As discussed in Chapter  3,  the baseline hazard assessment does account for  some
improvement in the profile of childhood lead exposure over the 50 year modeling time frame
to reflect the expected attrition of older housing stock where lead paint can still be found, with
a  concurrent  increase in the  number and proportion of newer  homes without lead paint.
However, it was assumed in the baseline hazard assessment that no property owners would
undertake specific abatements to  reduce or eliminate lead  currently present in paint, soil or
dust.1

       To estimate the benefits expected to result from abatements assumed to be induced by
the Section  403 hazard levels, a series of "what-if analyses were performed. Three sets of
assumptions were necessary to conduct these "what if' analyses.  These were:

       1)      A set of assumptions  defining decision rules incorporating  the  Section  403
              hazard levels;

       2)      A set of assumptions regarding the nature of the responses by property owners
              to  those hazard levels in  terms of  the specific  abatement actions to  be
              undertaken; and

       3)      A set of assumptions regarding  the change in children's exposure conditions as a
              result of undertaking those abatements.

       These three sets of assumptions are discussed further  in the following sections.
1      As noted in Chapter 3, this 'no abatements" assumption incorporated in the baseline analysis is
recognized as being extreme, since there are abatements of paint, soil and dust currently being performed in the
absence of these regulations.


Abt Associates, Inc.                           5-1                       Draft. January 10, 1994

-------
  5.1.1  Decision Rule Assumptions

        The first set of assumptions, regarding the selection of hazard levels to be evaluated,
  has been discussed in Section 3.4,  and is dealt with in detail in Chapter 6.  The specific
  decision rules addressed are summarized in Exhibit 5-1.

        As discussed in  Chapter 3.4 and Chapter 6, the specific  paint, soil and  dust values
  identified as the hazard levels in these decision rules were, with the exception of the 500/400/-
  option, arrived at through the consideration of the estimated net  benefits produced That is,
  among all of the three media combinations, two media combinations, and single media options
  of paint, soil and dust  hazard levels considered, the decision  rules with the hazard levels
  presented in Exhibit 5-1  were the ones that  maYimi™H net benefits, given  those  other
  assumptions.

        The  Voluntary Optimum decision rule is a special case in which no  specific hazard
  levels are set for paint, soil or dust; rather it  is assumed that individual property owners will
  choose to perform abatements that provide maximum positive net benefits, or will perform no
 abatement if none of the options produces positive net benefits.

        The hazard levels in the 500/400/- decision rule that is included in this analysis ttalfnot
 based on net benefits considerations.  Rather, it was based on an  individual risk perspective,
 using  the probability of exceeding  certain  critical blood  lead levels  as the "trigger" for
 inducing abatements.  Suppose for example that a  household facing an  abatement decision
 (i.e., expecting a child in the ensuing year) has lead paint in good condition at an XRF of 19,
 soil lead at 2,200 ppm, and dust lead at 1,100 ppm.  Since these values are just below those
 that would induce  abatement in any of these media according to the net benefits analysis,  it
 would be assumed under those decision rules that no abatement would be done.  However, the
 blood  lead geometric mean predicted by the  ffiUBK for a population of children exposed to
 these levels  is 15.3 Mg/dl. At this level, and assuming  a GSD  of  1.6, the probability of
 exceeding several frequently targeted blood lead levels of concern are:

              81.7% chance of exceeding 10 /*g/dl
              51.7% chance of exceeding 15/ig/dl
              28.4% chance of exceeding 20 jtg/dl
              14.8% chance of exceeding 25 /*g/dl

       Because one of the primary objectives  of setting hazard levels is to reduce or eliminate
 children's risk of adverse health effects due to lead exposure from  these  sources, and because
 CDC now considers blood lead  levels down to 10 pg/dl to be of concern from a health effects
 standpoint, it was felt necessary to also include consideration of a decision rule in the benefits
 analysis that was  aimed  specifically  at minimizing the incidence of these  high  blood  lead
 levels, notwithstanding the net benefits of that rule.
Abt Associates. Inc.                           5-2                       Draft, January JO. 1994

-------
                   Exhibit 5-1.  Summary of Decision Rules and Hazard Levels
   Decision Rule
                   Description
                Basis
 Voluntary Optimum
 No specific hazard levels are set; individual properly
 owners undertake those abatements (if any) producing
 me maximum positive net benefits.
 This   decision   rule   produces   the
 maximum  net  benefits  of  all  rules
 considered.
 Paint Condition Only
 Interior  lead  paint in bad condition always  induces
 abatement, regardless of lead level; however, no hazard
 levels set for paint in  good condition, dust lead, or soil
 lead.
 Since all other decision rules (except the
 Voluntary  Optimum) include a  hazard
 level for paint based on  bad condition,
 mis decision rule provides a means oi
 discerning the portion of  the  benefits
 from those other rules contributed by this
 component.
 2300/1200/20
 Interior  lead  paint in bad  condition always  induces
 abatement, regardless of lead level; and hazard levels
                       set at:
                            Soil = 2,300 ppm
                            Dust = 1,200 ppm
                            XRF = /OTfor paint in good condition
 This decision rule was found to have the
 highest   net   benefits   among   all
 combinations  considered  that  included
 specific hazard levels for all three media,
 with paint condition included.
 2300/-/20
 Interior leacK-p&nt in bad  condition always  induces
 abatement, regardless of lead level; and hazard levels
                       set at:
                            Soil =2,300 ppm
                            Dust = no level set
                            XRF = 20 for paint in good condition
 This decision rule was found to have the
 highest   net   benefits   among   all
 combinations  considered  that  included
 specific hazard levels for soil  and good
 condition paint,  with  paint  condition
 included.
 -71200/20
 Interior lead paint in bad  condition always induces
 abatement, regardless of lead level; and hazard levels
                       set at:
                            Soil = no level set
                            Dust = 1200 ppm
                            XRF = 20 for paint in good condition
 This decision rule was found to have the
 highest   net   benefits   among   all
 combinations  considered  that  included
 specific hazard levels for dust and good
 condition paint,  with  paint  condition
 included.
 2300/1200/-
Interior lead paint in bad condition always induces
abatement, regardless of lead level; and hazard levels
set at:
     Soil = 2,300 ppm
     Dust = 1,200 ppm
     XRF = no level set
                                                                           This decision rule was found to have the
                                                                           highest   net   benefits   among   all
                                                                           combinations considered  that  included
                                                                           specific hazard levels for soil and dust,
                                                                           with paint condition included.
 2300/-/-
Interior lead paint  in  bad condition  always induces
abatement, regardless of lead level; and hazard levels
                       set at:
                           Soil = 2,300 ppm
                           Dust = no level set
                           XRF = no level set
This decision rule was found to have the
highest   net    benefits   among   all
combinations  considered  that included
specific hazard levels for soil only, with
paint condition included.
-M200/-
Intenor lead paint  in  bad condition  always induces
abatement,  regardless of lead level; and hazard levels
set at:
    Soil = no level set
    Dust = 1,200 ppm
    XRF <= no level set
                                                                          This decision rule was found to have the
                                                                          highest   net   benefits   among   all
                                                                          combinations  considered  that  included
                                                                          specific hazard levels for dust only, with
                                                                          paint condition included.
-/-/20
Interior lead  paint  in  bad condition  always induces
abatement,  regardless of lead level; and hazard levels
                       set at:
                           Soil = no level set
                           Dust = no level set
                           XRF = 20 for paint in good condition
This decision rule was found to have the
highest    net    benefits    among    all
combinations considered  that included
specific hazard levels for good condition
paint, with paint condition included.
SOO/400/-
                       Interior  lead  paint in bad condition always  induces
                       abatement, regardless of lead level; and hazard levels
                       set at:
                           Soil = 500 ppm
                           Dust = 400 ppm
                           XRF = no level set
                                                   This  decision  rule  was  designed  to
                                                   minimize individual risk  of exceeding
                                                   specific  target blood  lead  levels  (see
                                                   discussion in text).
Abt Associates, Inc.
                               5-3
              Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
        Shown in Exhibit 5-2, below, are  back-calculations of the value for the geometric
 mean that will keep 90%, 95%, or 99% of the population below the specific blood lead target
 of 10,  15, 20 and  25 jtg/dl (assuming in all cases a GSD of 1.6).   So, for example, for an
 individual child to have _>_ 90% chance that his or her blood lead will not exceed 10 /tg/dl (or,
 conversely,  < 10% chance that it will  exceed 10 /tg/dl),  that child's exposure conditions
 should lead to an estimated geometric mean blood lead value of 5.48 /tg/dl or less.  Similarly,
 to have a 95% chance of having a blood lead below 15 /£g/dl, the predicted geometric mean
 for those exposure conditions should be less than 6.92 /ig/dl.
               Exhibit 5-2.     Geometric Means (in /tg/dl) to Achieve
                                Indicated Blood Lead Targets


PbB target: 10 /tg/dl
15 /tg/dl
20 /xg/dl
25 MR/dl
GM to keep
90% of
population
below
indicated PbB
target
GM to keep
95% of
population
below
indicated PbB
target
GM to keep
99% of
population
below
indicated PbB
target
(Assumes a GSD of 1 .6)
5.48
8.21
10.95
13.69
4.62
6.92
9.23
11.54
3.35
5.03
6.70
8.38
       Given the most recent guidance provided by  CDC for blood lead levels of concern,
goals were assumed for a set of lead hazard levels that will limit individual risk of exceeding
key target blood lead levels to:

       Approximately 90% chance of blood lead less than 10 /tg/dl, and
       Approximately 95% chance of blood lead less than 15 /tg/dl, and
       Approximately 99% chance of blood lead less that 20 /tg/dl.

       Considering the geometric means in Exhibit 5-2, these goals would be met by the blood
lead geometric means in the bolded cells.  For the purpose of this analysis,  a value in the
middle of this range of 6.5 /tg/dl has been selected as the target geometric mean blood lead to
approximate the above stated risk targets.

       Based on the IEUBK model runs, a series of soil and dust combinations were identified
that produce a geometric mean of approximately 6.5 /tg/dl.  These combinations included
some having very high dust levels in combination with low  soil levels (e.g., dust = 800 ppm;
soil = 11 ppm), and some having very high  soil levels  in combination with low dust  levels
(soil = 958 ppm; dust  = 25 ppm).  The specific hazard levels selected for this decision rule
Abt Associates, Inc.
5-4
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 were soil = 500 ppm and dust = 400 ppm, which avoided the extremes of combinations
 producing the same risk levels.  It should be noted that this decision rule also includes the
 assumption that lead paint in bad condition will always  induce abatement.  No hazard level
 was included for lead paint in good condition, since it was found that adding such a hazard
 level would not substantially affect the predicted blood lead levels (see Section 5.3).

       5.1.2  Abatement Choice Assumptions

       The second set of assumptions are also discussed  in part in Chapter 3.4 as well as in
 Chapter 4.  Briefly, it has been assumed that property owners facing an abatement decision
 will choose an abatement type that will reduce their paint, soil and/or dust levels to be in
 conformance with the Section 403 hazard levels,  and will  choose from among alternatives able
 to accomplish this goal, the abatement alternative that maximizes the net benefits.

       As described in Chapter 4,  there are 10 specific abatement choices considered in this
 analysis.  These include two paint  abatements (high-end  and low-end paint abatements); two
 soil abatements (high-end and  low-end soil abatements);  four  combined  paint  and  soil
 abatements (high-end paint with high-end soil;  high-end paint with low-end soil; low-end paint
 with high-end  soil; and low-end paint with low-end soil); and two  dust abatements (recurrent
 and non-recurrent).

       5.1.3  Post-Abatement Exposure Condition Assumptions

       The third set of assumptions,  those regarding the change in exposure conditions as a
 result of undertaking a specific type of abatement,  were  discussed in part in Chapter 4 with
 respect to the effectiveness of the various types of abatement considered.

       The assumed post-abatement conditions for each alternative are summarized in Exhibit
 5-3. Post-abatement conditions for the combined paint and soil abatements simply reflect the
 combination of post abatement conditions for  each  separately.  The "calculated" dust values
 referred to in Exhibit 5-3  are explained below.

       It is generally recognized that the lead present in dust in homes originates  primarily
 from lead in paint at that home and in  the soil  in proximity to that home.  As discussed in
 Chapter 4,  we  have  assumed that all  paint and soil  abatements will  also  include dust
 abatement.   Therefore,  whenever  homes perform abatements of paint or soil, there is an
 expected concomitant reduction in the level of  lead in the dust in that home.  It was therefore
 necessary to incorporate  an algorithm in the  benefits analysis  to  estimate what those post-
 abatement dust levels would be.
Abt Associates, Inc.                          5-5                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
       Exhibit 5-3.
Summary of Post-Abatement Conditions for
      Various Abatement Alternatives
       Abatement Alternative
               Assumed Post-Abatement Conditions
 High End Paint Abatement
       • Paint:
       •Soil:
No interior lead paint remains.
No change in soil lead concentration.
Uses lower of HUD value or calculated value.
 Low End Paint Abatement
       • Paint:  No lead paint on windows; intact lead paint
               remains on other surfaces.
       • §eU:   No change in soil lead concentration.
       • Dust:  Uses lower of HUD value or calculated value.
 High End Soil Abatement
        Paint:  No change  in  interior  lead  paint  levels oi
               condition.
        Soil:  Lead concentration reduced to 100 ppm.
        Dust:  Uses lower of HUD value or calculated value
 Low End Soil Abatement
        Paint:  No change in interior lead paint levels of
              condition.
        §pjl :  Lead concentration reduced to 500 ppm
        Dust:  Uses lower of HUD value or calculated value.
 Recurrent Dust Abatement
        Paint:  No change in interior lead paint levels of
              condition.
        SoU:   No change in soil lead concentration.
        Dust:  Lead concentration reduced to 100 ppm.
Non-recurrent dust
      • Paint:  No change in interior lead paint levels of
              condition.
        Soil:   No change in soil lead concentration.
        Dust:  Reduced to calculated value.
Abt Associates, Inc.
             5-6
                        Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
       The algorithms used were based on relationships provided in the December 1991 draft
 Guidance Manual for the ffiUBK model. The basic relationships provided there were:

                       PAD = [366 + (83.5. (PbP -1.0))]+ [0.9• PbS ]        (Equation 5-1)

 where PbD is the dust lead concentration in ppm; PbP is the maximum interior paint XRF
 measurement; and PbS is the soil lead concentration in ppm.

       In the Guidance Manual, this relationship is modified slightly for low XRF values. If
 the XRF value is greater than 0 but less than or equal to 1, the equation becomes:

                                PbD = 252 + [0.9 • PbS ]                  (Equation 5-2)

       If there is no lead paint (i.e., XRF = 0), the relationship is:

                                   HO = [0.9 • PbS]                     (Equation 5-3)


       Two exceptions exist to using  these calculated post-abatement dust levels.  The first is
 in the case  of  recurrent  dust abatement.  Because it is  assumed that the recurrent dust
 abatement option is undertaken for the express purpose of minimizing dust lead levels without
 performing  any  paint or soil abatement,  it was necessary to make an assumption as  to the
 effectiveness of this option.  It is assumed in this case that the recurrent dust abatement will
 yield an effective dust level is 100 ppm.

       The  second exception to  using  these  calculated  dust  values  for  post-abatement
 conditions  is when the original  HUD dust value is lower  than  the post-abatement value
 calculated from the above algorithms.   In these cases, the lower HUD value was used to avoid
 having an outcome where the post-abatement dust level exceeded the baseline dust level.

       As noted in Chapter 3,  the risk modeling (and therefore the benefits modeling as well)
 cannot at present differentiate between the health damages to children whose soil lead exposure
 is predominately bare  soil from the  damages  to  children  whose  exposure  is mainly from
 covered soils. As discussed in Chapter 3, no information is available to differentiate between
 bare and covered soils in the baseline  risk assessment. It is assumed, however, that the post-
 abatement soils are all grass-covered.   Because the intake of lead from exposure to bare soils
 is expected to be greater than  from exposure to covered soils (all other  factors  being equal,
 such as lead concentration and soil type),  the benefits of soil abatement may be underestimated
 for those cases where the starting condition is bare soil,  and overestimated where the starting
 condition is covered soils.  As noted  in Chapter 3,  it is assumed that these factors largely
 compensate for one another in the aggregate estimate  of the baseline damages and the benefits
 of soil  abatement.  It is not known,  however, how reasonable this assumption  is, since neither
 the  distribution of the incidence of bare vs. covered soils in residential settings, nor  the
 relationships between soil condition and blood lead levels are known. In Chapter 7, this issue
Abt Associates, Inc.                           5-7                      Draft. January 10, 1994

-------
 is discussed further in the context of its potential effects on benefit-cost  comparisons and
 identifying hazard levels that maximise net benefits.
 5.2    BENEFITS MODELING PROCESS

        The modeling process for estimating the benefits resulting from various combinations
 of decision rules and abatement choices parallels that described in detail in Chapter 3 for the
 baseline hazard assessment.   Consider, for example, the first year of the SO year modeling
 time frame.  In the baseline hazard assessment, the first year's cohort of children are assumed
 to experience exposure to lead in paint, soil and dust as estimated from the HUD data and
 other assumptions described previously. In essence, the abatement decision being made in the
 baseline  assessment  in anticipation of these  new  children arriving is  "no  abatement."
 Alternative analyses were therefore performed to calculate the effect of undertaking each of the
 10 viable abatement options at each of these homes.  To do this,  the baseline levels of lead in
 paint,  soil,  and/or dust were  replaced  with  the assumed post-abatement conditions,  as
 summarized in Exhibit 5-3.

        Using these post-abatement paint,  soil and dust lead levels, the modeling  process is
 then identical to that used in the baseline hazard assessment. That is, these reduced exposure
 levels are used in the ffiUBK model, maintaining all other ffiUBK assumptions as before,  to
 arrive at a new, lower estimate of the geometric mean for subpopulations of children in each
 housing category.  These lower geometric means, again with the assumption of a geometric
 standard deviation  of 1.6, are used  to define  the blood  lead distribution for these children.
 Using the first year cohort of children, an estimate is made of the incidence of IQ points lost,
 cases of  IQ < 70,  incidence of blood  leads  >  25 jig/dl,  and  neonatal mortality.   As
 discussed in Chapter 3, the estimated incidence of these effects for the remaining 49 years  of
 the modeling  time  frame are obtained through the use of multipliers that reflect anticipated
 changes in birth rates and housing stock levels over the full modeling period.

       As  indicated before,  the benefits for undertaking a particular  set of abatements  in
 response to a given decision rule is calculated as the difference between the baseline estimate
 of the  incidence of these effects and the  estimates obtained  with  the assumed abatements
 having been performed.

       It  is important to note that  in  modeling the benefits and  costs of hazard level /
 abatement choice combinations, we assume always that when abatements are done, they are
 only done in conjunction with the anticipated arrival of a new child in the ensuing year.  That
 is, abatements are not assumed to be done on homes just because they exceed the lead paint,
 soil and/or dust hazard levels. The imminent arrival  of a  new  child  is assumed  to be the
 trigger  for making abatement decisions, using the Section  403  hazard levels to guide the
 specific abatement  choice.  It is also important to note that  the modeling of benefits has
 assumed that property  owners facing an abatement decision will always choose to perform
 some abatement if they exceed specified hazard  levels (i.e., there are no non-compliers).
Abt Associates. Inc.                          5-8                       Draft, January 10,1994

-------
       This section presents the estimated benefits of the various Section 403 decision rules in
 terms of impacts on population blood lead levels and avoided incidence of the specific adverse
 health effects addressed, namely IQ point loss, IQ  < 70, blood lead > 25 pg/dl, and neonatal
 mortality.    For the purpose  of comparing the different  decision rules,  the blood  lead
 distribution changes and avoided incidence estimates presented in this section reflect only the
 first model year. Since the multipliers used to determine the avoided incidence of these effects
 across the entire modeling  period are the same for the baseline  and all post-abatement
 scenarios, the relative order of benefits is the same in the first year as it would be over the full
 modeling time frame.

       Since most of the benefits computed are directly associated with  the  changes  that
 abatements have on the population blood lead distribution,  it is useful  to first  compare  how
 different decision rules affect the blood lead distributions.  Exhibit 5-4 provides a summary
 comparison of the blood lead distributions for the baseline with  those resulting from  the
 various decision rules for the first model year cohort. One general observation about the blood
 lead changes (which applies to most other measures of benefits as well) is that the inclusion in
 a decision rule of the XRF = 20 hazard level for paint  in good condition has little or no effect
 on the estimated benefits relative to a similar decision rule without the XRF constraint.

       The largest downward shifts in the blood lead distributions were observed in the  two
 "special case" decision rules, i.e., the Voluntary Optimum and the 500/4007- rule. The latter
 of these had the greatest impact, with a predicted downward shift in the geometric mean from
 a baseline value of 4.06 fig/dl to 2.45 pg/dl.  The Voluntary Optimum  was close behind  this
 with  a  downward shift in the geometric mean to a  value of  2.52 pg/dl.   However,  the
 500/400/- decision rule  has a much larger impact in terms of reducing the size of the upper tail
 of the distribution, showing  for example only about 2.4%  of the population expected to be
 above 15 /*g/dl,  versus 9.0%  above this  level for the Voluntary Optimum.

       Among the several three-media, two-media and single-media decision rules based on
 maximum net benefits,  the largest effects are seen for the options that include both soil  at
 2,300 ppm and dust at 1,200 ppm. Again, adding an XRF = 20 hazard level for paint in good
 condition has no significant effect on the predicted blood lead distribution.  The decision  rule
 options with dust of 1,200 without a soil hazard level results hi a greater downward shift in the
 blood lead distribution than the options with  a soil hazard level of 2,300  without a dust hazard
 level.  The least effective decision rules are those that place a hazard level only on paint in
 good condition, with no constraints on either soil or dust.        It should also be noted  that
 while the downward shift in the geometric mean is greater for the Voluntary Optimum than for
 these  rules based on maximum net benefits,  all  of these  latter rules have lower predicted
 GSDs, and consequently result  in slightly lower portions of the population  in the upper tail
 than predicted for the  Voluntary Optimum.  This  is primarily a  result of the underlying
 assumption that,  in the rules based net-benefits, all homes with lead paint in bad condition  will
 undergo abatement when a  child is expected,  an assumption  that is not included in  the
 voluntary optimum.


Abt Associates. Inc.                            5-9                       Draft. January 10, 1994

-------
Exhibit 5-4. Summary of Post-Abatement Blood Lead Distribution Characteristics by Decision Rule
Decision Rule
Baseline
Voluntary
Optimum
Paint Condition
Only
Soil = 2300
Dust = 1200
XRF = 20
Soil = 2300
Dust = 1200
No XRF value
Soil = 2300
No Dust Value
XRF = 20
No soil value
Dust = 1200
XRF = 20
Soil = 2300
No Dust value
No XRF value
No soil value
Dust = 1200
No XRF value
No soil value
No dust value
XRF = 20
Soil = 500
Dust = 400
No XRF value
Mean
6.08
4.11
5.75
4.64
4.64
5.58
4.73
5.58
4.73
5.75
3.24
Geometric
Mean
4.06
2.52
3.82
3.30
3.30
3.78
3.32
3.78
3.32
3.82
2.45
Geometric
Standard
Deviation
2.45
2.70
2.47
2.35
2.35
2.43
2.37
2.43
2.39
2.47
2.20
Median
3.91
2.45
3.72
3.36
3.36
3.71
3.36
3.71
3.36
3.72
2.56
90th
Percentile
13.30
9.47
12.55
9.67
9.67
11.99
9.81
11.99
9.81
12.55
6.43
95th
Percentile
18.83
13.39
17.73
12.78
12.78
16.65
13.19
16.65
13.19
17.73
8.12
% > 10
Mg/dl
15.96%
9.05%
14.63%
9.24%
9.24%
13.87%
9.57%
13.88%
9.57%
14.62%
2.39%
% > 15
Mg/dl
8.01%
3.81%
7.12%
3.13%
3.13%
6.33%
3.54%
6.33%
3.54%
7.12%
0.39%
% > 20
Mg/dl
4.35%
1.72%
3.77%
1.16%
1.16%
3.16%
1.50%
3.16%
1.50%
3.77%
0.08%
% >25
Mg/dl
2.46%
0.82%
2.08%
0.46%
0.46%
1.67%
0.69%
1.67%
0.69%
2.08%
0.02%
Mote: All decision rules except the Voluntary Optimum also include paint in bad condition as a hazard level regardless of XRF value;
XRF values shown in the above decision rules refer to good condition paint.

-------
        Exhibit S-S summarizes the effect of these rules in terms of avoided IQ point loss and
 avoided incidence of IQ < 70 for the first year cohort.  In terms of IQ point losses avoided,
 the order of benefits obtained by the decision rules is  identical to that observed for the
 downward shifts in the blood  lead  distributions.    The 500/4007-  decision rule and the
 Voluntary Optimum show avoided IQ point losses in the first year of about 2.8 million and 1.9
 million, respectively.  It is noteworthy that the 2300/1200/20 and 2300/1200/- decision rules
 have slightly lower total avoided IQ point losses of about 1.4 million, but that the average IQ
 point loss per affected individual is almost 2 points, versus about 1.6 points per individual for
 the 500/400 and voluntary optimum rules.

        The  benefits in terms of avoided incidence of IQ  < 70 deviates  slightly  from the
 avoided IQ point losses in that the Voluntary Optimum ranks slightly  below the 2300/1200/20
 and 2300/1200/- decision rules.  This  is in large part due to the effect of the larger residual tail
 in the Voluntary Optimum  discussed previously coupled with the piece wise linear regressions
 used to estimate the incidence of IQ < 70 which has a higher probability at higher blood lead
 levels.
        Similarly, in the avoided incidence of blood lead levels above 25 ng/dl (Exhibit 5-6),
 the general  order is similar, but in this  case the Voluntary  Optimum falls below both the
 2300/1200/20 and 2300/1200/- rules, as well as the -/1200/20 and -/1200/- rules. Again, this
 is  the  effect of  the Voluntary Optimum   including no  high end paint abatements  noted
 previously.

        Exhibit 5-7 provides a summary of the resulting impact of the various decision rules on
 limiting the  individual risk of children to elevated blood lead levels. As indicated there, it is
 estimated that in  the baseline (no abatement) case, about  960,000 children in the first year
 cohort  are born into homes where the predicted geometric mean blood lead levels  are above
 6.5 ftg/dl. Assuming a GSD of 1.6 for these homes,  the individual risk of exceeding 10 /tg/dl
 is 18.0% or greater, of exceeding 15 /zg/dl is about 4.76% or greater, and of exceeding 20
 /*g/dl is about 0.85%  or greater.  As shown in Exhibit 5-7, the 500/400/- decision rule
 eliminates all cases of homes where the expected blood lead GM is .>. 6.5 /tg/dl, which was
 the  specific  intent of this particular  decision  rule.   The  other decision  rules  result in
 approximately 600,000 to 880,000 of the baseline 960,000 children in the first model year
 being bom into homes where paint, soil and dust levels imply GMs at or above 6.5 /ig/dl.

       Exhibit 5-8 shows the  avoided incidence of neonatal mortality for the various decision
 rules.  Most of the decision rules result in essentially identical benefits of avoiding 48 or 49
 cases of neonatal  mortality in the first year cohort.  These neonatal mortality cases avoided
 result almost entirely from  the required  high end  paint  abatement  in homes  having bad
 condition lead paint2 .  The 500/400/- decision rule has a somewhat higher benefit of 75 cases
 avoided, owing to the need to perform additional high-end paint abatements beyond those for
       The current model assumptions for neonatal mortality associate this adverse effect with the presence of
any interior lead paint in the home.  Since only high-end paint abatement eliminates all interior lead paint, only
high-end paint abatement will provide the benefit of reduced incidence of neonatal mortality.


Abt Associates. Inc.                           5-11                       Draft, January 10. 1994

-------
 homes having bad condition in order to meet the more stringent dust level of 400 ppm.  The
 Voluntary Optimum is notable in that no cases of neonatal mortality are avoided, since this
 option results in no high-end paint abatements being performed.   (Note that in the baseline
 estimate there are about 330 neonatal deaths in the first year as a result of maternal exposure to
 lead paint.)
Abt Associates, Inc.                           5-12                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                  Exhibit 5-5.  Summary of Avoided IQ Point Loss and
                     Avoided Incidence of IQ < 70 by Decision Rule
Decision Rule
Baseline
Voluntary Optimum
Paint Condition
Only
Soil = 2300
Dust = 1200
XRF = 20
Soil = 2300
Dust = 1200
No XRF value
Soil = 2300
No Dust Value
XRF = 20
No soil value
Dust = 1200
XRF = 20
Soil = 2300
No Dust value
No XRF value
No soil value
Dust = 1200
No XRF value
No soil value
No dust value
XRF = 20
Soil = 500
Dust = 400
No XRF value
IQ Point Loss
Avoided (First
Model Year
Cohort)
0
1,912,011
319,818
1,404,490
1,402,677
492,439
1,318,269
490,626
1,316,456
321,631
2,751,452
Affected
Population of
Children (First
Model Year
Cohort)1
0
1,482,732
370,074
714,261
708,989
428,048
683,096
422,776
677,824
375,346
1,736,524
Average IQ
Point Loss
Avoided (First
Model Year
Cohort)
0
1.34
0.86
1.97
1.98
1.15
1.93
1.16
1.94
0.86
1.58
Avoided Cases
of IQ < 70
0
5,434
1,081
5,308
5,305
1,912
4,877
1,909
4,874
1,084
8,823
1 Total population in first model year cohort = 3,877,530
Abt Associates, Inc.
5-13
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
          Exhibit 5-6.  Summary of Avoided Incidence of Blood Lead > 25 pg/dl
                                    by Decision Rule
Decision Rule
Baseline
Voluntary Optimum
Paint Condition Only
Soil = 2300
Dust = 1200
XRF = 20
Soil = 2300
Dust = 1200
No XRF value
Soil = 2300
No Dust Value
XRF = 20
No soil value
Dust = 1200
XRF = 20
Soil = 2300
No Dust value
No XRF value
No soil value
Dust = 1200
No XRF value
No soil value
No dust value
XRF = 20
Soil = 500
Dust = 400
No XRF value
Avoided Incidence of FbB > 25 /ig/dl
0
63,422
14,744
77,479
77,479
30,736
68,513
30,736
68,513
14,745
94,656
Abt Associates, Inc.
5-14
Draft, January 10,1994

-------
         Exhibit 5-7. Summary of Children hi First Year Cohort Remaining hi
                 Homes with Paint, Soil and Dust Lead Levels Implying
                    Geometric Mean Blood Lead Levels _>_ 6.5 /tg/dl
Decision Rule
Baseline
Voluntary Optimum
Paint Condition Only
Soil = 2300
Dust = 1200
XRF = 20
Soil = 2300
Dust = 1200
No XRF value
Soil = 2300
No Dust Value
XRF = 20
No soil value
Dust = 1200
XRF = 20
Soil = 2300
No Dust value
No XRF value
No soil value
Dust = 1200
No XRF value
No soil value
No dust value
XRF = 20
Soil = 500
Dust = 400
No XRF value
First Year Cohort of Children Remaining in
Homes with Predicted GM _> 6.5 pg/dl
< 0.85% chance of PbB > 20
< 3.76 % chance of PbB > 15
< 18.0% chance of PbB > 10
(assuming GSD =1.6)
960,066
607,312
883,301
636,768
636,768
861,764
636,768
861,764
636,768
883,301
0
Abt Associates, Inc.
5-15
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
            Exhibit 5-8. Summary of Avoided Incidence of Neonatal Mortality
                                    by Decision Rule
Decision Rule
Baseline
Voluntary Optimum
Paint Condition Only
Soil = 2300
Dust = 1200
XRF = 20
Soil = 2300
Dust = 1200
No XRF value
Soil = 2300
No Dust Value
XRF = 20
No soil value
Dust = 1200
XRF = 20
Soil = 2300
No Dust value
No XRF value
No soil value
Dust = 1200
No XRF value
No soil value
No dust value
XRF = 20
Soil = 500
Dust = 400
No XRF value
Avoided Incidence of Neonatal Mortality
(in First year Cohort of Children)
0
0
48
49
48
48
49
48
48
48
75
Abt Associates, Inc.
5-16
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 5.4    VALUATION OF BENEFITS

        In Section 5.3, above, the discussion of health damages associated with childhood lead
 exposure, and the benefits of reducing that exposure, focused on the incidence of adverse
 health effects in terms of blood lead distributions,  IQ point losses, avoidance of IQ < 70, and
 neonatal  mortality.  To provide a basis for comparing the magnitude of the benefits resulting
 from paint, soil and dust abatements with the estimated cost of conducting those abatements, it
 is necessary to place a monetary value on the benefits.   This section describes how  these
 benefits have been monetized.

        5.4.1  Valuing Lost IQ Points

        Available economic research provides little empirical data  for society's willingness to
 pay (WTP) to avoid a decrease in a child's IQ.  As an alternative measure, it was assumed that
 IQ deficits incurred through lead exposure will  persist throughout the exposed child's lifetime.
 Two consequences of this IQ decrement, representing a portion of society's full willingness to
 pay, are  then considered:  the  decreased present value of expected lifetime earnings for the
 child,  and the increased educational  resources expended for a- child who becomes mentally
 handicapped or is in need of compensatory education as a consequence of lead exposure.  The
 value of foregone earnings is addressed in this section.

        The reduction in IQ has a direct and indirect effect  on earnings.  The direct effect is
 straightforward  - lower IQs  decrease job attainment and  performance.   Reduced IQ also
 results  in reduced educational attainment,  which, in turn,  affects earnings and labor force
 participation.  Note that these effects  on earnings  are additive since the studies used for this
 analysis have controlled for the direct and indirect effects separately.

       Direct Effect of IQ on Wage Rate

        Henry  Aaron,  Zvi Griliches,  and Paul  Taubman  have reviewed  the literature
 examining the relationship between IQ and  lifetime earnings (USEPA  1984). They  find that
 the direct effect, (schooling held constant)  of IQ  on wage  rates ranged from 0.2 percent to
 0.75 percent. Perhaps the best of these studies is Griliches (1977).3   He found the direct effect
 of IQ on  wage rates to be slightly more than 0.5 percent per IQ point.  Because this value is
 roughly the median estimate of the USEPA review of the literature, it is the value used in this
 analysis.

       Indirect Effect of IQ on Earnings

       From Needleman et al.  (1990)  it is possible to estimate the change in years of schooling
 attained per one IQ point change.  Their regression coefficients for the effect of tooth lead on
       Griliches used a structural equations model to estimate the impact of multiple variables on an outcome of
interest.  This method has conceptual advantages over other empirical estimates used in the literature because it
successfully controls for the many confounding variables that can affect earnings.


Abt Associates, Inc.                           5-17                      Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 achieved grade provide an estimate  of current grade achieved.  However, many of these
 children  were in college  at  the time  and are expected to achieve a  higher  grade  level.
 Following Schwartz (1990a), after adjusting the published results for the fact that a higher
 percentage of children with low tooth lead were attending college, a 0.59 year difference in
 expected maximum grade achieved between the high and low exposure groups was estimated.
 It is assumed that educational attainment relates with blood lead levels in proportion to  IQ.
 The difference in IQ score between  the high and low exposure group was 4.5 points.  By
 dividing 0.59/4.5 = 0.131, it suggests that the increase in lead exposure which reduces IQ by
 one point may also reduce years of schooling by 0.131 years.4

       Studies that estimate the relationship  between educational attainment  and wage rates
 (while controlling for IQ and other  factors) are less common.   Chamberlain and Griliches
 (1977) estimate that a one year increase  in schooling would increase wages by 6.4 percent. In
 a longitudinal study of 799 subjects over 8 years, Ashenfelter and Ham (1979) reported that an
 extra year of education increased the  average  wage rate over the  period, by 8.8 percent.
 Conservatively, we use a lower bound by assuming one year of additional schooling increases
 the wage rate by 6 percent. To arrive at the indirect effect of increased schooling, increased
 wages per IQ point is calculated using: (6 percent wage increase/school year) x (0.131 school
 years/IQ) = 0.786 percent increase in wages per IQ point.

       There  is  one  final indirect  effect on earnings.   Changes in IQ affect labor  force
 participation.  Failure to graduate high school, for example, correlates with participation in the
 labor force, principally through higher unemployment rates and earlier retirement ages.  Lead
 is also  a strong correlate  with attention span deficits, which likely  reduce  labor  force
 participation.  The results of Needleman et al. (1990) relating lead to failure to graduate high
 school can be used to estimate changes in earnings due to labor force participation.  Using the
 odds ratio from Needleman et al., it  was estimated that a one IQ-point decrease would also
 result in a 4.5 percent increase in the probability of failing to graduate. Krupnick and Cropper
 (1989) provide estimates of labor force participation between high school graduates and non-
 graduates, controlling for age, marital status, children, race, region, and other  socio-economic
 status factors. Based on their data, average participation in the labor force is reduced by 10.6
 percent for persons failing to graduate from high school.  Because labor force participation is
 only one component of lifetime earnings (i.e., earnings = wage rate X years of work), this
 indirect effect of schooling is  additive to the  effect on wage rates.  Combining this estimate
 with the Needleman result of 4.5 percent increase in the risk of failing to graduate high school
 per IQ point, indicates that the mean impact of one IQ point loss is a (10.6% x 4.5%) = 0.477
 % decrease in expected earnings from  reduced labor force participation.

      Combining the direct effect on wage rates of 0.5 percent  with the two indirect effects
 (0.786%  for less  schooling and 0.477%  for reduced labor force participation) yields a total of
 1.76 percent decrease in earnings for every loss of one IQ point.
4      Following Schwartz (1990a), this analysis uses the Needleman (1990) to quantify the change in grade
achievement from lead exposure.


Abt Associates. Inc.                           5-18                       Draft, January JO, 1994

-------
       Value of Foregone Earnings

       In the next step to monetize intelligence effects, the percent earnings loss estimate must
 be combined with an estimate of the present value of expected  lifetime earnings.   Data on
 expected lifetime earnings as a function of educational attainment and sex was reported for the
 U.S. population in 1979 by the Bureau of the Census (USDOC 1983).  Given the distribution
 of the 1979 population with respect to age, educational attainment, and sex, Census used age
 specific employment rates and average wage rates to estimate annual earnings as a function of
 age, sex and education.  Assuming various rates of real wage growth (productivity effect) and
 discount factors, the annual earnings stream from age 18 to age 64 was collapsed to a series of
 estimates of the present value of lifetime earnings using an assumption of 1 percent real wage
 growth and a 7 percent discount rate.  Men tend to earn more than women because  of higher
 wage rates and higher labor force participation.  However, for both men and women, expected
 lifetime earnings increase greatly with education.

       The  Census  estimates were  expressed in  1981  dollars   and  assumed  that  the
 age/education specific employment and average wage rates would remain constant over time.
 A number of issues must  therefore be addressed  in updating the Census  estimates to 1990
 dollars.  First,  educational attainment has changed since 1979, with a greater proportion of the
 population attending college, especially a greater proportion of women.  Second, wage rates
 have increased both due to productivity effects (real  wage growth) and  inflation. Third, age-
 specific employment rates may have changed.  Women, in particular,  are likely to have higher
 rates of labor force participation than in 1979.

       In revising the  Census estimates, the  first issue was addressed  by using more recent
 data on education.  USDOC (1992)  provides  data  on educational  attainment  for  the 1991
 population. For this analysis, data on the population over age 25 were used in order to remove
 the influence of those individuals too young to have completed schooling. The population data
 were used as weighting factors to derive a sex  and education weighted average of expected
 lifetime earnings.  So constructed, the weighted average adjusts the  estimate based on 1979
 data to current levels of educational attainment.  Lifetime earnings were thus calculated to be •
 $177,000 for the average  work force participant.    The  next step in adjusting the earnings
 estimate is to apply an adjustment for wage growth to update from 1981 to 1990 dollars.  The
 Bureau of Labor Statistic's Employment Cost Index rose from a level of 67.2 in 1981 to 105.4
 in 1990, an  increase of about 57 percent.  Updating the average lifetime earnings  to 1990
 dollars yields a revised estimate of $277,616.

       While more recent age, sex, and education-specific employment  rates could be used to
 re-estimate labor force participation, a complete analysis would require steps to dampen the
 effects of cyclical unemployment.  Such an exercise would require considerable effort and is
 beyond the scope of this analysis.  To the extent that labor force participation has increased for
 specific groups since 1979, the adjusted value presented here underestimates the true expected
 lifetime earnings.  For  example,  if the percentage of female children  eventually joining the
permanent workforce  is greater than the percentage of women over age 25  that worked in
Abt Associates, Inc.                          5-19                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 1979, the expected lifetime earnings of female children would be greater than estimated in this
 analysis.

       Note that use of earnings is an incomplete measure of an individual's value to society.
 Those individuals who choose not to participate in the labor force for all of their working years
 must be accounted for, since the lost value of their productive services may not be accurately
 measured by wage rates.   The largest group are those who remain at home doing housework
 and child rearing.  Also, volunteer work contributes significantly to social welfare and rates of
 volunteerism tend to increase with educational  attainment and income.5   If the opportunity
 cost of non-wage compensated work is assumed to be the average wage earned by persons of
 the  same  sex,  age,  and education,  the average  lifetime earnings estimates would  be
 significantly higher  and  could be  approximated  by  recalculating  the tables  using  full
 employment rates for all age/sex/education groups.  To be conservative, only the value of lost
 wages is considered in this analysis.

       The adjusted value of expected lifetime earnings obtained above is a present value for
 an individual entering the labor force at age 18 and working until age 64.  Because a lead-
 induced IQ decrement occurs in infancy or  childhood, the $277,616  figure must be further
 discounted to the specific age at  which the health effect is measured and  adjusted for the
 probability that the infant would survive to age  18.  For an infant less than one year old, the
 present value of lifetime earnings discounted at seven  percent at age 18 and adjusted for
 survival would be $80,587. Combining this value with the estimate of percent wage loss per
 IQ point yields: $80,587 x 1.76 percent loss/IQ  point = $1,414 per lost IQ point.

       5.4.2 Valuing Increased Educational Resources

       There are two categories of increased educational resources needed as a result of lead
 exposure.  First, lead exposure  results in an  increase in the number of children  with IQs less
 than 70 (note that IQ is not measured until age 7).  As  these children grow older, they will
 need an education program tailored to the  mentally handicapped.  In addition, some children
 whose blood lead is greater than 25  pg/dl  will need additional  instruction while attending
 school later in life.

       Children with IQs Less  than 70

       To value the reduction  in the number of infants with IQs less than 70, the reduction in
 education costs were measured - a clear underestimate of the total benefits.6  Kakalik et al.
 (1981), using data from a study  prepared for the Department of Education's Office of Special
 Education  Programs,  estimated that  part-time  special  education costs  for children  who
 remained in regular classrooms  cost $3,064 extra per child per year in 1978.  Adjusting for
 changes in the GNP price deflator yields an estimate of $6,318 per child in 1990 dollars.  For
5      Statistical Abstract of the United States, 1986. Table No. 651, p. 383.
6      The largest part of this benefit is the parents' willingness to pay to avoid having their child become
mentally handicapped, above and beyond the increased educational costs.


Abt Associates, Inc.                           5-20                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
the calculations, this incremental estimate of the cost of part-time special education was used to
estimate the cost per year per child needing special education as a result of impacts of lead on
mental development.  Costs would be incurred from grades 1 through 12.  Discounting future
expenses at a rate of 7 percent yields an expected present value cost of approximately $33,346
per child (assuming compensatory education begins at age 7 and continues through age 18).
Note that this is an underestimate  of the cost,  since Kakalik et al. measured the increased cost
to educate children attending regular school -  not a special education program.

       Children with Blood Lead Levels > 25 pg/dl

       When calculating the cost of compensatory education,  three relatively  conservative
assumptions were made.  First, it  is assumed that no children with blood lead levels below 25
jtg/dl would require compensatory education  later in life.  This is conservative since many
studies show cognitive effects at IS  pg/dl.  Second, it is assumed that only 20 percent of the
children above 25  pg/dl would be  severely  affected enough to  require and receive some
compensatory education.  Third,  based on several follow-up studies that showed cognitive
damage persists for three years or more, even after blood lead levels are lowered,  it is assumed
that each child  who needed compensatory education  would require it for three  years (age 7
through 9).

       For this analysis it is assumed 20 percent of the children with PbB  > 25 pg/dl will
receive  compensatory education for three years, but after that, will not.7  The Kakalik et al.
(1981) estimate  of part-time special education costs for children who remained in  regular
classrooms is also used to estimate the cost of compensatory education for children suffering
low-level cognitive damage.   As  indicated above, adjusting for changes in the GNP price
deflator yields an estimate of $6,318 per child in 1990 dollars. Discounting future costs at a
rate of 7%  annually yields a present value estimate of $11,048 in 1990 dollars.

      5.4.3 Valuing Neonatal Mortality

      The value of avoiding a statistical death used in this analysis is $2 million. This value
is based on the lower estimate of a range of values provided in a review of studies quantifying
individual's willingness to pay  to avoid risks to life by Fisher et al. (1989).  The Fisher et al.
lower bound estimate of $1.8 million in 1986  dollars is adjusted for inflation and real  income
growth to 1992 dollars using the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) implicit price index.
5.5    COMPUTING BENEFITS FOR FULL MODEL PERIOD

       In Chapter 3, we provided a detailed description of the procedures used to inflate the
results obtained for the first year of the modeling time frame to arrive at the results for the
overall 50 year modeling period.  As discussed there, the incidence of adverse effects (such as
7      See U.S. EPA (1986) for more detail on the data sources and the nature of the assumptions made to
quantify this benefit category.


Abt Associates, Inc.                           5-21                      Draft. January 10, 1994

-------
 number of IQ points lost, cases of IQ < 70) obtained in the first model year in homes with
 lead paint are multiplied by a factor of 48.65, and by a factor of 99.60 for homes without lead
 paint to obtain the full 50 year incidence.  The benefits of the various decision rules expressed
 in terms of avoided incidence of these effects can also be determined for the full model period
 by applying these factors to the avoided incidence calculated for the first model year in lead
 paint and non-lead paint homes.

       To estimate the total value of the benefits over the  full 50 year time frame, a similar
 pair of multipliers is applied to the value of the benefits obtained for the abatements performed
 in the first model year. The expression for computing the total benefits is  similar to that given
 in Chapter 4 for computing total costs:
where:
       Vt is the total value of the benefits
       Ali is the avoided incidence of the specific effect of concern;
        ,* is the undiscounted unit value of the benefit in 1990 dollars, adjusted for additional
              expected children in homes getting abated;
       r  is the discount rate, here 7%.

       The  adjustment for additional expected  children noted above that is included in the
undiscounted unit value of the benefits is included in recognition of the potential benefits to
future children bom into those homes after the abatement is performed in response to the first
births in those homes.    As noted in Chapter 3,  for each "first born" child in a home, there is
an expected number of an additional 1.55 children in that  same home over a subsequent 49
year period.   Therefore,  for each  $1.00 in benefits for the  first born child, an additional,
undiscounted $1.55 in benefits is expected for the abatement performed on that home (i.e., this
would be the value if those additional children were born in the same year as the first child).
To account for the expectation that those additional children will be born at some later time, it
is necessary to discount that amount.  Discounting that additional $1.55 over the ensuing 50
years with a 7% discount rate, and taking the average of those discounted values results in an
estimated additional benefit  of approximately $0.50 for each  $1.00  in  first  year  benefits.
Therefore, the undiscounted unit benefit cost provided in Section 5.4 are multiplied by  1.5 for
inclusion in Equation 5-4 , above.

       Using procedures similar to those described in Chapter 3, the multipliers obtained are
8.80 for homes with lead paint, and 12.48 for  homes without lead  paint.  That is, the total
value of the benefits is obtained by applying these multipliers to the undiscounted unit value of
the monetized benefit calculated for the abatements performed in the first model year.
Abt Associates. Inc.                           5-22                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
5.6    RESULTS OF MONETIZED BENEFITS

       Exhibit 5-9 provides a summary of the total monetized benefits for the various decision
rules considered over the full modeling period.  As indicated by the values shown there, the
order of the decision rules based on total monetized benefits is similar to the order obtained
from consideration of changes in the blood lead distribution and avoided IQ point losses.

       The largest benefits, totaling $66.7 billion, axe achieved by the 500/400/- decision rule,
followed by the Voluntary Optimum  at $48.2 billion. The benefits for the 2300/1200/20 and
2300/1200/- rules have nearly identical benefits of $35.0  and $34.9 billion, respectively.
Following these closely are the -/1200/20 and -/1200/- rules  with benefits of $33.0 and $32.9
billion. Considerably lower total benefits are estimated for the 2300/-/20 and 2300/-/- rules,
each with approximately $11.2 billion.  Lastly, the -/-/20 and the paint condition only rules
are estimated to produce total benefits of approximately $7.4 and $7.3 billion, respectively.

       Exhibit  5-10  displays the relative contribution of the monetized value of each  of the
categories of benefits based on the first model year abatements for each decision rule. The
relative contributions of the benefits categories are comparable for the entire modeling period.

       By far, the major contribution to the value of the benefits derives from the avoided loss
of IQ points. For all of the decision  rules, this component of the benefits contributes between
75 % and 90% of the value of the benefits.  The contributions of the avoided incidence of IQ
< 70  and of blood lead levels > 25 /tg/dl are comparable  for each decision rule, generally
contributing between 5% and 7% of the total benefits each.

       The most variable contributor to the value of the benefits is avoided neonatal mortality.
Except for the  Voluntary Optimum and the 500/400/- decision  rules, the  monetized value of
these  benefits  are comparable,  approximately $140 million for the first year.  For the
Voluntary  Optimum, neonatal mortality avoidance makes  no  contribution,  while for the
500/400/- rule the value is about $220 million.  Excluding the voluntary optimum,  the avoided
neonatal mortality benefits as a percentage of the total are lowest for those decision rules with
the lowest total benefits, and highest for those with the lowest benefits.  For example, in the
Paint  Condition only rule, the first year benefits are estimated to be about $890 million, and
the neonatal mortality benefit at $138 million comprises about  16%  of the total. By contrast,
the 2300/1200/20 rule has total first year benefits of $3.5 billion, of which neonatal mortality
at $141 million is only 4%  of that total. For the 500/400/- rule, where the total  first year
benefits are highest at $6.6 billion, and the neonatal mortality is also highest among all rules at
$220 million.  However, as a percent of the total, these benefits constitute only about 3.3% for
the 500/400/- rule.
Abt Associates, Inc.                           5-23                      Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
               Exhibit 5-9. Summary of Monetized Value of Benefits for
                     Full Modeling Time Frame by Decision Rule
Decision Rule
Voluntary Optimum
Faint Condition Only
Soil = 2300
Dust = 1200
XRF = 20
Soil = 2300
Dust = 1200
No XRF value
Soil = 2300
No Dust Value
XRF = 20
No soil value
Dust = 1200
XRF = 20
Soil = 2300
No Dust value
No XRF value
No soil value
Dust = 1200
No XRF value
No soil value
No dust value
XRF = 20
Soil = 500
Dust = 400
No XRF value
Value of Benefits over
Full Modeling Time Frame
($ Million)
$48,190
$7,319
$34,984
$36,920
$12,249
$33,009
$11,186
$32,949
$7,383
$66,688
Abt Associates, Inc.
5-24
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
              Exhibit 5-10. Distribution of Monetized Benefits by Category for

                                  First Model Year Abatements.
              1.1
              €> -°

              3 ~
              < eg
              .- c
              H
              § •
              CO £
$2
$1

$0
                                                                     Total Benefits
                                                                    Avoided Q Loss
                                                                  Avoided Neonatal Mortality
                                                                 .voided PbB =26
                                                               Avoided Q<70
           Avoided IQ<70
    | Avoided PbB ^5
                                             Avoided Neonatal

                                             Mortality
                                                              Avoided IQ Loss
                                                                               Total Benefits
Abt Associates, Inc.
                         5-25
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                             6. BENEFIT-COST ANALYSIS
       The objective of this chapter is to evaluate alternative sets of criteria which are expected
 to induce abatements of lead-contaminated soil, dust, and paint.  These sets of criteria are called
 decision rules. For paint, its condition is taken as the primary criterion. For soil and dust, the
 criteria, called hazard levels, are expressed as concentrations of  lead.   This chapter also.
 considers the possibility of making levels of lead contamination in paint a criterion for inducing
 abatement.

 6.1   BASIS FOR EVALUATION

       The two previous chapters have presented the costs and benefits of different types of
 abatements applied to homes with varying levels of lead in soil, dust, and paint and with paint
 in varying conditions. While benefits and costs are of independent interest, considering benefits
 or costs alone does not permit an evaluation of economic efficiency.  On the contrary, it is not
 unusual for the decision rule generating the greatest benefits to have the highest costs, possibly
 even costs that exceed the benefits. It is also not unusual for the rule having the least costs to
 generate very small benefits.  To produce significant benefits it may be necessary to expend
 significant resources.

       To determine which circumstances are the ones that warrant a significant expenditure of
 resources requires that the benefits and costs be considered in tandem. Considering them in the
 form of net benefits (benefits minus costs) provides a basis for determining whether society will
 be better off by implementing any particular decision rule.  Comparing different decision rules
 on the basis of their respective  net benefits  provides a means  for  identifying the best
 opportunities to improve economic efficiency. For this benefit-cost analysis, net  benefits were
 calculated for thousands of different combinations of hazard levels for soil, dust, and paint.1
 This chapter focuses its attention on the decision rules that generate the highest net benefits.

 6.2    ALTERNATIVE DECISION RULES

       The  abatement choices made under  different decision  rules  in this analysis can be
 characterized in terms of differences in the information that the public is assumed to have.  At
 one extreme, the public is assumed to have access to the same information that was used in this
 analysis: the blood lead levels expected among children if abatement does not take place; the
 blood lead reductions achievable from different abatement scenarios; the  monetary values of
 these blood lead reductions; the cost of the  alternative abatement approaches; and the levels of
 lead in soil, dust, and paint and the condition of paint in the home.  At the other extreme, all
 households are assumed to know lead levels and paint condition but only the households that are
1       There are 14,972 different combinations of 30 soil concentrations, 20 dust concentrations, and 22 paint
concentrations.  Each combination constituted a potential decision rule in the benefit-cost analysis.  Two other
decision rules were also considered, a "voluntary optimum* and a qualitative hazard level based on paint condition,
bringing the total to 14,974 different decision rules considered.

Abt Associates. Inc.                           6-1                        Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 expected to abate (since their levels exceed candidate hazard levels and/or their paint is in bad
 condition) have the set of information necessary to choose the abatement alternative that yields
 the highest net benefits.  Implicitly this assumes an ability to calculate benefits and costs for
 abatement alternatives.  However,  such  a  calculation by  households may not  actually be
 necessary. In practice, any household that chooses to abate will need to seek guidance regarding
 the combination of soil, dust, and point abatements that is appropriate to its circumstances.

 6.2.1  Voluntary Optimum Decision Rule

        The first decision rule considered in this analysis generates the highest net benefits of all
 decision rules evaluated.  It serves as the benchmark against which all alternative decision rules
 can be judged.  This decision rule is called  the voluntary optimum because  it is based upon
 households' determining which abatement alternative generates the highest net benefit and their
 voluntarily choosing to undertake that  optimal abatement.   Decisions under the voluntary
 optimum are assumed to draw upon sufficient information to determine whether it is optimal to
 abate and if so, to choose the  optimal abatement alternative.   In subsequent decision rules,
 households are assumed to  have less information and therefore less leeway to choose on their
 own, instead being induced by EPA's hazard levels to initiate abatements of certain types. The
 evaluation of the voluntary optimum indicates that a substantial number of households would find
 it in their vested interest to have their homes abated.2

 Examples

       To illustrate the implications of allowing households to choose their abatements this way,
 examples for particular households  are presented in  Exhibit  6-1.   Home  A has a mean
 concentration of lead in soil of 8,800 ppm, mean concentration of interior dust of 1,100 ppm,
 and lead-based interior paint that is in damaged condition and  has  an XRF reading  of  11.
 Relevant choices for this house are: high-end paint abatement, low-end paint abatement, high-end
 soil abatement, low-end soil abatement,  recurrent  dust  abatement, four combined abatements
 (high-end paint abatement and high-end soil abatement,  high-end paint abatement and low-end
 soil abatement, low-end paint abatement and high-end soil abatement,  low-end paint abatement
 and low-end soil abatement). Nonrecurrent dust abatement is not a viable option because paint
 and soil would remain sources of lead contamination.
       The gross benefits considered by each household were assumed to include not only the private benefits
accruing to that household from current and future members but also the social benefits accruing to any household
living in the home in the 50 years after the birth of the child that is triggering the abatement decision. Based upon
a 7% discount rate, a substantial portion of the benefits from abatement, approximately 69%, are associated with
protecting the first child alone.  (For households having additional children,  the private proportion of the social
benefits will be higher.)  In many cases,  net benefits can be positive when  only this portion of the  benefits is
compared to costs. Where that is not the case, there is also the prospect that the homeowners can recoup all or part
of their abatement costs in an increased value of the home at the time of sale. This increased value may stem from
the possibility that the new owner places a premium on having a lead-abated home, from the spillover improvements
in the home that come from certain types of abatement (such as the aesthetic improvements that come from high-end
paint abatement),  or from both.


Abt Associates. Inc.                             6-2                         Draft, January JO,  1994

-------
       Under the voluntary optimum, home A chooses low-end soil abatement, which generates
 net  benefits  of $3,607.   High-end soil abatement  would  generate  higher benefits  but
 disproportionately higher costs, so much so that the resulting net benefits are negative.  The
 damaged condition of paint does not justify paint  abatement.  Consequently, paint abatement
 options generate negative net benefits, with the exception of combining low-end soil and low-end
 paint abatement. This combination results in positive net benefits but lower than what can be
 accomplished by low-end soil abatement alone since low-end paint abatement generates negative
 net benefits.3

       After the abatement, soil levels would be 500 ppm, predicted dust levels are still above
 1000 ppm since paint contamination has not been abated, and  some soil contamination still
 exists. No further abatements appear to be warranted.   As indicated above, undertaking paint
 abatement in addition to soil abatement generates negative net benefits. Additional abatement
 directed at the remaining dust, through recurrent dust abatement,  also generates negative net
 benefits.

       Home B has approximately the same dust contamination as home A (1000 ppm) but no
 lead-based paint and soil contamination of only 100 ppm. The only relevant abatement choices
 for this home are recurrent and nonrecurrent dust.  The former is not needed since there is no
 known major source of lead.  Negative net benefits for recurrent dust abatement reflect this
 phenomenon.   Instead, nonrecurrent dust abatement is  chosen since it generates positive net
 benefits of $2,614. After abatement, this home will have dust and soil levels of 100 ppm.

       Home C provides  an example where  dust abatement is optimal even where  lead
 contamination is present in soil and damaged interior paint as well as in dust.  This example
 illustrates the substitutability among lead abatements for different media.  For each of the three
 media (soil, dust, and paint), some form of abatement could be selected that produces positive
 net benefits.  These are low-end paint abatement, high-end soil abatement, recurrent  dust
 abatement, and nonrecurrent dust abatement.   Choosing  the latter generates the highest net
 benefits, $2,555, more than twice the net benefits from the next best alternative - low-end paint
 abatement.  Being able to exploit the substitutability by choosing the one with the highest net
 benefits is one key to the high net benefits  of the voluntary optimum.  Inducing households to
 meet medium-specific targets can reduce the achievable net benefits.  For example, by setting
 a soil hazard  level of 1100, it is assumed that the owner of home C  would be induced to
 undertake high-end soil abatement since this is the only means for getting below this specific
 hazard level.
       The net benefits of combining low-end soil and low-end paint abatements are higher than the sum of each
of these abatements alone because the blood lead reductions implied by a given change in a lead source are not
constant. They are lower at higher levels.

Abt Associates. Inc.                           6-3                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                                                      Exhibit 6-1

                                       Examples of Abatement Chokes Under the Voluntary Optimum Decision Rule
Home

A

B


C


D


E
Soil
ppm
8800

100


1100


0


800
Dust
ppm
1100

1000


3300


200


1200
Paint
nig/
en1
11

0


5


20


1
Condition

Damaged

Intact


Damaged


Damaged


Intact

HP
(9336)

N/A


(4046)


(6227)


(8349)

LP
(2203)

N/A


1208


55


(2144)

HS
(9364)

N/A


157


N/A


(3055)
Net Benefits ($1990)
LS
3607

N/A


(1587)


N/A


(5181)
RD
(«6«3)

(4312)


92


(7307)


(4138)
HP/HS
(13963)

N/A


(«145)


N/A


(12097)
HP/LS
(2466)

N/A


(8062)


N/A


(14015)
LP/HS
(10520)

N/A


(1689)


N/A


(5782)
LP/LS
2356

N/A


(3240)


N/A


(7912)
NRD
N/A

2614


2555


N/A


(161)
Selected
AhafflamMf

Low-Cad
Sofl(LS)
Non-
Recurrent
Dot (NRD)
Non-
R0cwnnt
Dust (NRD)
Low-
End Paint
(LF)
None
Kev
HP = High-End Paint Abatement
LP = Low-End Paint Abatement
HS =• High-End Soil Abatement
LS = Low-End Soil Abatement
RD = Recurrent Dust Abatement
HP/HS = High-End Paint Abatement and High-End Soil Abatement
HP/LS = High-End Paint Abatement and Low-End Soil Abatement
LP/HS - Low-End Paint Abatement and High-End Soil Abatement
LP/LS = Low-End Paint Abatement and Low-End Soil Abatement
NRD  = Nonrecurrent Dust Abatement
The designation of N/A for net benefits means that either the associated abatement is not applicable because no lead is
present from the source abated (i.e., soil, dust, or paint) or that the initial level of lead is at or below the assumed post-
abatement level. In either case, abatement of the source produces no benefits.
Abt Associates, Inc.
          6-4
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
       In the voluntary optimum, paint abatement is the optimal choice in only a few homes.
 Home D illustrates the special circumstances where low-end paint abatement was the optimal
 choice.  Essentially, paint abatement is the best choice because neither soil abatement nor dust
 abatement is relevant.   There is little or no  contamination in these media; therefore no
 substitutability among media to abate can be exploited. Paint abatement is also justified because
 the XRF reading is so high. The latter results in expected damages from pica,  which is assumed
 to have a 25 % chance of being exhibited by the first child born into this home after abatement,
 that are large enough to justify abatement.  The net benefits from low-end paint abatement are
 small but positive.

       The final example, home E, shows that choosing not to abate can also be an optimal
 choice, even when there is lead contamination in each of the three media - 800 ppm in soil, 1200
 ppm in dust, and a maximum XRF of 1 for interior paint.  It is optimal not to abate because
 each abatement alternative has negative net benefits.  This outcome further  underscores how
 other decision rules besides the voluntary optimum lead to lower net benefits.  For example,
 suppose  that a decision rule were constructed based upon a soil level of 800  ppm and that the
 owner of home E is induced to abate because this  level has been set by  EPA.  At best, this
 homeowner could expect to achieve only negative net benefits, -$3,055.  In  the aggregate, if
 there are a large number of homeowners in similar circumstances, this particular hazard level
 can  lead to  a substantial portion  of the induced  abatements having negative net benefits.
 Consequently, how well a particular set of hazard levels performs relative to others in terms of
 aggregate net benefits depends on how well it can avoid inducing abatements in homes where
 they are  not warranted.

 Results for the Voluntary Optimum

       Over the course of the 50 years of births modeled in this analysis, 45 million abatements
 would be initiated under the voluntary optimum  decision rule.   As indicated in Exhibit 6-2,
 approximately 99% are nonrecurrent dust abatements.  Initial lead concentrations in the dust
 range from 200 to 5,900 ppm. Lead concentrations in soil are less significant, ranging from 100
 to 1,100 ppm. Low-end soil abatements account for a little more than 1 %.  In these homes, soil
 concentrations,  which  are much   higher than for the homes receiving nonrecurrent dust
 abatement, range from  3,000 to  8,800  ppm.   Dust  concentrations, which  can be affected
 indirectly by soil abatement, range from 1,100 to  5,800.  The small  remaining fraction of
 abatements entail  low-end paint abatement.  As anticipated from the example cited above, the
 interior XRF readings are high (20 to 22) and the dust and soil levels for the paint-abated homes
 are low.  Among the homes where  the choice is made not to abate, the maximum contamination
 levels can be as high as 3,100 ppm for soil, 2,500 ppm for dust,  and an XRF of 22 for paint.

       The  present discounted  value of the  net benefits  under the  voluntary  optimum is
 approximately $34 billion. These results imply average discounted benefits of $1,067, average
 discounted  costs  of $308, and average discounted net benefits of $759.  The discounted net
 benefits per home range from a low of $11 to a high of $13,126.

       These figures do not reflect the testing and  inspection costs that are a prerequisite to
 determining what, if any, abatement is justified in a home. To determine lead levels in soil and
Abt Associates, Inc.                           6-5                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 dust in all homes where a birth is imminent and paint levels in homes where a birth is imminent,
 the undiscounted cost of testing is $713.

        Ideally this cost would be included in the benefit-cost calculation made for each house.
 While the testing costs have to date not been included, subtracting the total testing costs from
 the total net benefits provides a sufficient evaluation given certain assumptions.  Excluding
 testing costs from the individual abatement decision could have a significant effect on the gross
 benefits but possibly not the number of abatements.  Given estimated testing costs of $713 per
 home, it is assumed that some homeowners would not choose to test if the expected pay-off from
 the test (the likelihood of a positive test result times the net benefit from the best  abatement
 choice)  is less than the cost of testing.  Following this kind of logic in the modelling would
 likely lower the testing costs, the number of abatements, and the benefits and costs.  However,
 for homeowners who choose to test without  regard to the expected pay-off, the number of
 abatements would not change.  When the net benefits of abatement are positive, abatement will
 be initiated. The testing costs are sunk costs  that do not affect the decision to abate.  In this
 situation, the number of abatements and the gross benefits may not be too different from that
 estimated currently for the voluntary optimum although the net benefits will.

       By subtracting the total testing costs of $24 billion from the total net benefits, it is
 possible to provide an estimate of net benefits under these circumstances.   The resulting overall
 net benefits of $10 billion from the voluntary optimum are still substantial.
Abt Associates, Inc.                           6-6                        Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                                                                           Exhibit 6-2
                                                                                        Voluntary Optimum
Abatement




Tolih
Statagr
Selected
Nona
LS
LP
NRD

Banalita
llnrillionl

2.789
26
45.376
48.190
Com
ItnrillionJ

1.802
26
11.878
13.888
•at Banatila
(•million)
0
787
0
33.487
34.284
Total Number
ol Abatemante
IIOOOi)
0
577
21
44.567
46.185
Proportion
ol
Abatemente

1.28%
0.05%
88.68%

Number of Abatemente
With Negative
0
0
0
0
0
• 	 a* 	 i j 	 a
Individ ml
MB! BsiMfitti
0
670
47
11

Maximum
Individual
NetBenelita
0
8.843
55
13.126

Minlmuni
Soil Level
taunj
0

0
0

Maximum
Soil 1ml
fepm)
3.100
6.800
100
1.100

MI_iL«_B
ininiiniin
Duet level
fern)
0
1.100



ML
Hiaumun
Dual Laval
2.500

400


Minimum
Interior Paint
ft 	 i ___n
0
0
20
0

Maximum
Interior Paint
22
11
22
13

Abate
        ntCo
HP -  High Paint Abatement
LP - Low Paint Abatement
HS -  High Sol Abatement
LS - Low SoB Abatement
RD -  Reeumnt Duet Abatement
HP/HS • High Paint, High Soil Abetomente
HP/IS - High Petal, Low Soil Abatement.
LP/HS - tow Paint. High SoB Abatemente
LP/LS » Low Paint. Low SoB Abatemante
NH D »  Nonreemrent Duet Abatement

-------
 6.2.2  Decision Rules Based Upon Induced Abatements

        Since the current rate of abatement does not appear to be as great as that implied by the
 voluntary optimum, it  is reasonable to wonder what interventions are necessary to induce
 homeowners to initiate abatement. Section 403 of TSCA proposes hazard levels that have the
 potential to serve as a  means of inducing abatement.  The strong assumption made in this
 analysis is that owners of homes  where any given hazard level is exceeded and where a child
 is about to be born will be induced to abate.

        To evaluate a particular set of candidate hazard levels that EPA might consider setting,
 this analysis characterizes these  levels as restrictions  to  the behavior modelled  under  the
 voluntary optimum. For example, suppose that the Agency were to set a soil hazard level of
 1100 ppm and a dust hazard level of 1200 ppm.  Using these criteria  as constraints on each
 household's decision of whether and how to abate, this analysis identifies  the highest net benefits
 achievable while adhering to EPA's hazard levels.  Relative to the pure voluntary optimum, this
 circumstance reflects a constrained optimization. Therefore, the net benefits will be lower since
 households may be induced by EPA's guidance to make abatement choices which had lower or
 even negative net benefits under the voluntary optimum.  Referring to Exhibit 6-1 again, home
 E would be induced by this set of hazard levels, particularly the 1200 ppm threshold for dust,
 to undertake dust abatement even  though the net benefits are negative.

       Since EPA's promulgation of hazard  levels does  take the form  of guidance for most
 households and does not  bind any household to  adhere to them,  the circumstances  of the
 individual  household's  decisionmaking are assumed to  be  different in  this  constrained
 optimization that they were under the voluntary optimum.  The difference can be described in
 terms of differences in the information households are assumed to have  about the benefits and
 costs of lead abatement.  Since information is costly to the household, the assumption of perfect
 information  being available to  the  household is  a  strong one.   By providing guidance to
 households in the form  of hazard levels at which  abatement should be  undertaken, EPA can
 lower the actual information costs  for the household abatement decision.  However, rather than
 providing each household with perfect information, the hazard levels promulgated by EPA would
 serve as general  guidance and  not the type  of  information that allows each household to
 determine exactly what is best.

       The result is that some households will make the same abatement choice as they would
 if they  had perfect information,  some  will be induced to  choose a form of abatement that
 provides lower  net benefits, and some will be induced to abate when they would have chosen
 not to under the voluntary optimum. Taking the candidate hazard levels mentioned (soil = 1100
 ppm and dust = 1200 ppm), these outcomes can be illustrated using the homes highlighted in
 Exhibit 6-1.  Home A exceeds the soil hazard level. No change in behavior is necessary since
 low-end soil abatement, which was chosen under the voluntary optimum,  is sufficient to reduce
 soil contamination below this threshold. Home C exceeds both the soil and dust thresholds. The
 optimal choice under the  voluntary  optimum, nonrecurrent dust abatement, does not address soil
 contamination.  Consequently, the best choice that allows getting below both thresholds is high-
 end soil abatement, which has positive net benefits  of $157 but these  are lower than those
 achievable through nonrecurrent dust abatement ($2,555).  Finally,  the example of home E,


Abt Associates, Inc.                           6-8                        Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 where no abatement is optimal under the voluntary optimum,  would be induced to choose
 nonrecurrent dust abatement, with negative net benefits (-$161), to meet the dust hazard level.

       Taken together, the overall net benefits for these three homes of selecting abatements are
 positive.  For the full  set of homes considered in  this analysis,  the overall net benefits of
 selecting abatements based upon a particular set of candidate could be positive or negative.  Only
 by setting hazard levels specific to each house is it possible to replicate the voluntary optimum.
 Since it does not yet appear feasible for EPA to  structure the hazard levels it promulgates this
 way, a simpler and more general set of hazard levels were assumed to be more likely.

       One important objective of this analysis was to identify sets of hazard levels of different
 types which compromised least the net benefits achievable under the pure voluntary optimum.
 The sets of hazard levels, referred to as decision rules, are of four types.  See Exhibit 6-3.  The
 first type of decision rule addressed paint condition.  It assumes that all homes with non-intact
 paint will undertake paint abatement. The second type of decision rule included this criterion
 as well as a hazard level for each of the three media that are addressed by this rule - soil, dust,
 and paint.  In Exhibit 6-3, these are labeled  "single-medium constrained."  The third type of
 decision rule encompasses hazard levels for two media, as well as condition.  The fourth type
 of decision rule addresses all three media and condition. Each of these will be considered in
 turn.
                                      Exhibit 6-3
                              Taxonomy of Decision Rules
Decision Rules
Condition
Constrained
Single-Medium
Constrained
Two-Media
Constrained
Three-Media
Constrained
Note: A "Yes" inc
rule.
Soil
(ppm)
—
Yes
—
—
Yes
Yes
—
Yes
Dust
(ppm)
—
—
Yes
—
Yes
—
Yes
Yes
Paint
(XRF)
—
—
—
Yes
—
Yes
Yes
Yes
icates that a hazard level is fixed for that particular med
Paint
Condition
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
urn in the decision
Abt Associates, Inc.
6-9
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 Qualitative Hazard Level for Faint Condition

        The first type of decision rule targets the condition of paint only.  Under this rule, only
 houses with non-intact paint are induced to abate.  Exhibit 6-4 presents the benefit-cost results
 for this decision rule. The total number of abatements only reflect the abatement of homes with
 lead-based paint in bad condition.  The abatement of other homes, which would be expected
 under the voluntary optimum, are not included, given the logic of this decision rule that only
 the qualitative hazard  level  will induce abatement.   Also, in  contrast with the voluntary
 optimum, certain homes are induced by the decision rule to undertake paint abatement even
 though this creates negative net benefits. Of the 7.1 million abatements induced by this decision
 rule,  6.7 million (95%) have  negative net benefits.  Overall, the net benefits for this decision
 rule were negative (-$17.3 billion).

        Exhibit 6-4 also shows the distribution of abatements by category.  Since the decision
 rule is specifically targeted at paint, only the paint abatement alternatives are chosen.4 High-end
 paint  is the optimal choice for 59% of the  homes; low-end paint is the choice in 39% of the
 homes.  Owners of other homes chose combinations of paint abatement and soil abatement, since
 these choices have higher net benefits than paint abatement alone.  The numbers of high-end and
 low-end paint abatements with negative net benefits are approximately proportional to the total
 numbers of abatements associated respectively  with each.

        Exhibit 6-4 also presents the abatement-specific net benefits, both in aggregate and the
 range of undiscounted values for individual homes.  These results underscore the difficulty with
 specifying an across-the-board rule.  There are cases of positive net  benefits for individual
 homes undertaking low-end paint abatement (where the maximum net benefits are $7,142), high-
 end paint abatement  (where  the maximum net benefit is  $2,629) and combined low-end
 paint/low-end soil abatements (where the maximum net benefits are $2,356).  However, the
 dominant outcome is that this decision rule entails substantial negative net benefits.  Of the 7.1
 abatements induced by this decision rule, 6.7 million (95%) generate negative net  benefits.
       Taken literally, a paint condition criterion requires abating pain in bad condition only.  Neither paint
abatement alternative used in this analysis is tailored particularly to abating deteriorating paint alone.  Instead, high-
end paint abatement entails complete and full abatement of interior lead-based paint and low-end paint abatement
involves full abatement of windows only. As such, the costs and effectiveness of these alternatives are taken as
proxies respectively for abatements addressing "extensive" and "limited" amounts of deteriorating paint.

Abt Associates, Inc.                            6-10                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                                                                               Exhibit 8 • 4
                                                                                          Pilnl Condition Criterion
hdueod
No
Fold:
suton
Bobctid
linn*
IHmB
IP
HPfl.8
Totol 60- Yoor
Bonollto
II million)
0
1.456
564
7.319
Total 60-Vur
Coolo
llmllllonol
0
20.134
1517
943
74
24.668
Totol 60-Voor
Not Bonollto
(Imllllanol
0
114.926)
12X1611
079)
17
117.349)
Totol Numbor
ol Abotomonto
(lOOO-ol
0
4.160
2.774
114
16
7X164
Proportion
ol
Abotomonto
56.88%
39.27%
1.61%
0.00%
Abotomonto
WlthNogotrm
Not Bonollto
IIOOO-o)
	 JD_
4JJ27
2.544
	 JJ4_
0
6.685
lodbbJnl
Not Bonollto
III
	 0
19.690)
12,657)

Morimin
IndMdal
Nit Binif Itt
in
	 0
2,829
7,142
U58
Mmknom
SollUvol
(ppml
	 0
0
0
3.100
8300
SoDlonl
(ppml
3.100
2.200
3.100
8.600
8.800
Minimum
OuotUnl
Ippml
0
0
1.100
•nxnm
DuolbMl
Ippml
6400
5400
1.100
laloriorPimt
1
1
11
Moxknm
mtortorPobri
Imalem')
22
11
AbMamani CodM
HP = High P.lnl Abnamenl
IP = Low Palm Abitamanl
HS " High Soil AbMamani
L8 = law Boll Abalomoni
RD » Reeurronl Dutt Abatanunl
HP/HS • High Palm. High Soil Abalamanla
HP/US . High Palnl. Low Soil AbalamonM
LP/HS = Low Paint. High Soil Abalomanta
IP/IS . Low Palm. Low Soil Abaiamonta
NR O • Nonracutram Dual Abaiamani

-------
 Single Medium Hazard Levels

        The effects of setting a hazard level for a single medium alone - for soil, dust, or paint -
  in addition to a qualitative hazard level for paint condition are considered in this section. While
 the intent of Section 403 is to set hazard levels for soil, dust, and paint, the results for these
 single-medium  decision rules  illustrate  that  the individual  media make  very different
 contributions to a three-media approach to addressing residential lead risks.  As will be shown
 below, decision  rules based upon two of the three individual media  (soil and paint)  lead to
 negative net benefits. The net benefits of the best dust hazard level are more than $20 billion
 higher than the net benefits of either the best soil or paint hazard levels.

        For each medium, a wide array of candidate decision rules are considered. Choosing the
 best among these alternatives is  based upon a comparison of net benefits.  For soil, the benefit-
 cost results for thirty alternative hazard levels ranging from 100 ppm to 3,000 ppm are given
 in Exhibits 6-5 and 6-6. For paint,  the results for twenty-two XRF readings from 0 to 21 are
 presented  in Exhibits 6-7 and 6-8.  For dust, the results for twenty alternative hazard levels
 ranging from 100 ppm to 2,000 are  presented in Exhibits 6-9 and 6-10.

        Given the framework of  a single-medium decision rule combined with a paint condition
 criterion, a hazard level of 2,300 ppm for soil would achieve the highest net benefits but these
 are negative (-$17.2 billion). Separate analyses indicate that the paint condition criterion is
 responsible for the bulk of the negative net benefits. This finding was anticipated from the earlier
 results showing  large negative  net  benefits from the previous decision rule  involving paint
 condition alone.

        The optimal hazard level for paint is an  XRF reading of 20 me/cm2 but again the net
 benefits are negative (-$17.6 billion).  While  there are homes having XRF levels equal to or
 greater than  20  whose owners  choose paint  abatement under the voluntary optimum, their
 number was  small (20,503) and they choose low-end paint abatement only.  In contrast, the
 owners of more than  4 million homes choose to conduct high-end paint abatement  because this
 decision rule combines the paint condition criterion  with the single-medium paint hazard level.
 Almost 95 %  of the induced abatements have negative net benefits.

       The best prospect among the single-medium decision rules is one based upon dust. A
 single hazard level of 1200 ppm for dust combined with the paint condition criterion generates
 net benefits of $3.3 billion. The  net benefits are higher for the single dust hazard level because,
 unlike the previous two cases, there is greater leeway for homeowners to choose abatements with
 higher pay-off, especially but not exclusively, the two forms of dust abatement.   Consequently,
 the accuracy of this decision rule in targeting homes with positive net benefits is higher. Of the
 15.6 million abatements induced by this decision rule, only  46% entail  negative net benefits.
Abt Associates, Inc.                           6-12                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
           Exhibit 6-5
Single Medium Hazard Levels: Soil
Decision Rules
Soil
(ppm)

2.900
2,800
2,700
2.600
2,500
2,400
2.300
2,200
2,100
2.000
,900
,800
,700
.600
,500
,400
1,300
1,200
1,100
1,000
900
800
700
600
500
400
300
200
100
Nonintact Paint
Abatement
Recommended
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
Benefits
($ millions)
9,983
,186
,186
,186
,186
,186
,186
11.186
14,645
15,240
15,240
15,240
15,240
15,240
15,571
15,571
15,750
15,906
16,864
17,091
17,441
18,708
18,708
20,539
20,628
21,211
31,968
34,207
37,582
40,049
Abatement
Costs
($ millions)
27,241
28,345
28,345
28,345
28,345
28,345
28,345
28,345
33,471
34,466
34,466
34,466
34,466
34,466
34,896
34,896
35,403
35,731
37,862
38,189
38,547
45,155
45,155
48,149
49,131
51,656
88,648
94,859
111,203
136,435
Net Benefits
($ millions)
(17,258!
(17,159!
(17,1591
(17,1591
(17,159]
(17,159!
(17,159]
(17,1591
(18,826]
(19,226]
(19,226)
(19,226)
(19,226)
(19,226)
(19,325)
(19,325)
(19,652)
(19,824)
(20,998)
(21,098)
(21,106)
(26,447)
(26.447)
(27,611)
(28,503)
(30,444)
(56,681)
160,651)
(73,620)
(96,386)
Total Number
of Abatements
(1000s)
7.750
8,069
8,069
8,069
8,069
8,069
8,069
8,069
10,139
10,486
10,486
10,486
10,486
10,486
10,649
10,649
10,761
10,828
11,445
11,513
11.586
13,189
13,189
14,104
14,320
14,883
16,922
18.777
23,259
29,157
Induced
Abatements
With Negative
7.154
7.154
7.154
7.154
7.154
7,154
7.154
7.154
9.224
9.571
9,571
9.571
9.571
9.571
9.734
9.734
9.845
9.913
10.530
10.597
10,606
12,209
12,209
13.124
13,340
13,912
16.722
18.577
23,059
28,958

-------
                      Exhibit 6-6
Single Medium Hazard Levels for Soil: Types of Abatement

Soil
(ppm)

2,900
2,800
2,700
2,600
2,500
2,400
2,300
2,200
2,100
2,000
,900
,800
,700
,600
,500
1,400
1,300
1,200
1,100
1,000
900
800
700
600
500
400
300
200
100
Nonintact Pain
Abatement
rlouulllllieiiuau
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES

(1000s)

4,160
4,160
4,160
4,160
4,160
4,160
4,160
4,160
4,147
4,147
4,147
4,147
4,147
4,147
4,147
4,126
4,113
4.113.
4,100
4,086
3,898
3,898
3,848
3,807
3,714
3,426
3,394
3,263
2,918
(1000s)
2,716
2,716
2,716
2,716
2,716
2,716
2,716
2,716
2,716
2.708
2,708
2.708
2.708
2,708
2.708
2.708
2,694
2,685
2,685
2,677
2,668
2,545
2,545
2,512
2,485
2,425
2,237
2,216
2,131
1,905
HS
(1000s)

0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
163
163
163
230
230
298
371
371
371
1,287
1,287
1,456
9,858
11,713
16,195
22,094
LS
(1000s)
686
,006
,006
,006
,006
,006
,006
,006
3,076
3,423
3,423
3,423
3,423
3,423
3,423
3,423
3,534
3,534
4,151
4,151
4,151
5.754
5,754
5,754
5,970
6,363
0
0
0
0
RD
(1000s)
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
HP/HS
(1000s)
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
13
13
26
40
40
40
90
90
122
847
879
1,010
1,355
HP/LS
(1000s)
114
114
114
114
114
114
114
114
114
126
126
126
126
126
126
126
147
147
147
147
147
336
336
336
377
438
0
0
0
0
LP/HS
(1000s)
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
	 Qj
0
0
0
0
0
8
8
17
26
26
26
58
58
80
553
574
659
885
^•^••^^•TB
LP/LS
(1000s)
74
74
74
74
74
74
74
74
74
82
82
82
82
82
82
82
96
96
96
96
96
219
219
219
246
286
0
0
0
0
NRD
(1000s)
0
o
0
o
o
0
o
o
0
0
0
o
0
0
0
0
o
o
0
0
0
o
0
0
0
0
o
0
0
0

-------
           Exhibit 6-7
Single Medium Hazard Levels: Paint
Decision Rules
Paint
(mg/cm1)
21
20
19
18
17
16
15
14
13
12
11
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
Nonintact Paint
Abatement
Recommended
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
Benefits
($ millions)
7,383
7.383
7,870
7,870
7,870
7,870
7,870
7,870
7,870
8,069
8,118
9,011
10.502
11,719
12.170
12,383
16,558
17,460
17,574
18,491
19,479
25,516
Abatement
Costs
($ millions)
25,013
25.013
27.605
27,605
27.605
27.605
27,605
27.605
27.605
27.837
28.300
29,398
33,541
36,420
37,767
39,188
42,626
43,908
45,164
50,874
60,588
102,784
Net Benefits
($ millions)
(17,631)
(17.631)
(19.735)
(19,735)
(19,735)
(19,735)
(19,735)
(19,735)
(19,735)
(19,767)
(20,182)
(20,387)
(23,039)
(24,701)
(25,597)
126,805)
(26,068)
(26,448)
(27,591)
(32,382)
(41,109)
(77,268)
Total Number
of Abatements
(1000s)
7,164
7,164
7,920
7,920
7,920
7,920
7,920
7,920
7,920
7,987
8,123
8,316
9,238
10,078
10,471
10,885
11,888
12,262
12,628
14,293
17,126
29,431
Induced
Abatements
With Negative
Benefits (1000s)
6,786
6,786
7.542
7.542
7,542
7,542
7,542
7,542
7,542
7,582
7,718
7,861
8,784
9.623
10,016
10,430
10,712
10,982
11,348
13,013
15,846
27,934

-------
                      Exhibit 6-8
Single Medium Hazard Levels for Paint: Types of Abatement
Decision Rules
Paint
(mg/cm1)
21
20
19
18
17
16
15
14
13
12
11
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
Nonintact Paint
Abatement
Recommended

YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
HP
(1000s)
4,221
4,221
4,678
4,678
4,678
4,678
4,678
4,678
4,678
4,719
4,801
4,841
5,116
5,624
5,861
6,112
6,719
6,945
7,166
8,174
9,888
17,332
LP
(1000s)
2,814
2,814
3,113
3,113
3,113
3,113
3,113
3,113
3.113
3,139
3,193
3,219
3,584
3,915
4,071
4,234
4,630
4,778
4,923
5,580
6,699
11,560
HS
(1000s)
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
LS
(1000s)
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
RD
(1000s)
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
HP/HS
(1000s)
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
HP/LS
(1000s)
114
114
114
114
114
114
114
114
114
114
114
190
474
474
474
474
474
474
474
474
474
474
LP/HS
(1000s)
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
LP/LS
(1000s)
16
16
16
16
16
16
16
16
16
16
16
65
65
65
65
65
65
65
65
65
65
65
NRD
(1000s)
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0

-------
           Exhibit 6-9
Single Medium Hazard Levels: Dust
Decis
Diiot
(ppm)
2.000
.900
.800
.700
.600
,500
,400
.300
,200
,100
,000
900
800
700
600
500
400
300
200
100
on Rules
Mnnin4af»t Point
Abatement
Recommended
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
Benefits
Ifi millinnat

26,227
26,227
26,227
26,366
28,342
28,846
29,669
31,413
32,945
35,856
37,227
41,932
43,145
46,438
49,416
58,373
63,230
64,003
71,579
77,260
Abatement

UOS1S
($ millions)
26,656
26,656
26,656
26.682
27,218
27,292
27,557
29,128
29,646
35.245
37,354
42,245
44.872
50.736
53.947
64,534
70.785
83,966
121,989
155,953
Net Benefits
I ft millions!
\9 minions I
(429)
(429)
(429)
(317)
1,124
1,554
2,112
2,285
3,299
611
(127)
(313)
(1,727)
(4,298)
(4,531)
(6,161)
(7,555)
(19,963)
(50,411)
(78,693)
Total Number
. ...
of ADBtements
(1000s)
12.370
12,370
12,370
12,446
13,351
13,564
13,954
14,654
15,602
17,634
17,909
20,378
21.019
23,506
25,962
34,334
43,883
51,978
63,963
83,759
Induced

Abatements
With Negative
Benefits (1000s)
6,753
6.753
6,753
6,753
6,762
6.762
6,803
7.031
7.114
8,491
8.781
9,149
9,625
11,209
12,168
15,402
19.756
22.796
30,267
44.358

-------
                     Exhibit 6-10
Single Medium Hazard Level for Dust: Types of  Abatement

Dust
(ppm)
2.000
,900
,800
,700
,600
,500
,400
1,300
1,200
1,100
1,000
900
800
700
600
500
400
300
200
100
Nonintact Paint
Abatement
Recommended
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
YES
HP
(1000s)
4,160
4,160
4,160
4.160
4,160
4,160
4,160
4,177
4,186
4,289
4,302
4,397
4,345
4,449
4,454
4,469
4,476
4,125
4,413
4,167
LP
(1000s)
2,766
2,766
2,766
2,766
2,757
2,757
2,783
2,740
2,731
2,627
2,572
2,516
2,329
2,239
2,192
2,087
1,998
1,894
1,190
692
HS
(1000s)
0
0
0
0
74
74
74
74
74
74
74
222
222
148
804
967
967
2,092
5,751
8,983
LS
(1000s)
91
91
91
91
91
91
91
411
411
411
411
411
411
1,028
1,028
3,098
3,379
0
0
0
RD
(1000s)
67
67
67
67
67
67
108
202
276
1,581
1,824
2,811
3,352
4,281
4,521
5,359
6,150
10,772
17.372
22,126
HP/HS
(1000s)
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
21
35
35
45
73
73
73
1,026
1,460
2,205
HP/LS
(1000s)
114
114
114
114
114
114
114
114
114
172
314
314
439
439
452
541
623
0
0
0
LP/HS
(1000s)
8
8
8
8
18
18
18
18
18
9
9
28
42
32
19
19
19
19
0
0
LP/LS
(1000s)
16
16
16
16
16
16
16
16
16
16
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
NRD
(1000s)
5.148
5,148
5,148
5.224
6,055
6,268
6.591
6,903
7,777
8,455
8.381
9,642
9,845
10.845
12.420
17,721
26,198
32,050
33,776
45,587

-------
        Exhibit 6-11 provides greater detail on the benefit-cost results for a hazard level of 1200
 ppm.  Of the 15.6 million abatements associated with this decision rule, 8.1 million (52%) entail
 dust abatement alone (recurrent or nonrecurrent).  It follows that the number of negative net
 benefits induced by this decision rule is a smaller percentage than was the case for either of the
 previous two decision rules, as indicated above.

        Most of the successful targeting of homes for abatement is associated with the choice of
 nonrecurrent dust abatement. Of the 7.7 million homes induced  to undertake recurrent dust
 abatement, 97% accrue positive net benefits.  While these abatements are substantial, the two
 other media are also addressed.  Furthermore, all of the high-end and low-end soil abatements
 generate positive net benefits, except when combined with paint abatement. The maximum net
 benefits per home are as high as $533 and $8,843 respectively for high-end and low-end soil
 abatement. All of the combined abatements involving high-end paint or high-end soil abatement
 have negative net benefits.  Finally, the vast majority of the high-end  and low-end paint
 abatements generate negative net benefits. Together, the net benefits of all high-end and low-end
 paint equal minus $17 billion.  Again, this result was anticipated from the evaluation of the
 decision rule based on a paint condition criterion alone.  Without the paint condition criterion,
 the net benefits of this decision rule would have been substantially higher.5
       It may be possible to improve the cost-effectiveness of paint abatement directed at non-intact paint and
consequently improve the overall net benefits. Currently, the benefit-cost analysis assumes that all paint in a home
will receive high-end paint abatement if there is non-intact paint that triggers abatement. More selective abatement
of non-intact paint only could  lower the costs of this  abatement  option without  compromising the benefits
significantly.  Net benefits would improve as a result.

Abt Associates, Inc.                            6-19                        Draft. January 10, 1994

-------
                                                                                             EihRiita-lt
                                                                                 SingU Medium Hanrd Lml: Out - 1200
•witMntnt

YM








Told
Soloctod

HP
IP
HS
18
RO
HPAS
IPIHS
ipas
NRD

BrnnlHi
llnilllonl

5.301
1.385
290
1.892
ws"
564
65
91
22.472
32.945
Coilt
llmilltonl

20.260
3,461
272
1.420
878
943
87
74
2.150
29.646
Mm* OatBulIlM
Mil BIMllw
Itmlllbiu)

114,9601
12.076)
19
472
(92)
0791
1221
17
20.322
3.299
of AbilMiinli
liooo-ii

4,188
2.731
74
411
276
114
18
16
7.777
16.601
Proportion
el
Abitominti

2&83%
17.50%
047%
2.63%
1.77%
0.73*
0.11%
0.10%
4934%

Abitominti
WIlhNogitln
NitBonoflta
IIOOO'i)
0
4.053
2.527
0
0
202
114
18
0
200
7.114
Mlnknam
hdMdMl
MM BiMf IH
in
0
0.690)
12.5571

670
13.528)
(8,5141
0.8011
1356
1130)

Mixknum
MMdnl
HilBiMllte
l«)
0
2.629
7.142
533
8.843
1.694
12468
11.689)
USB
13.126

SoD Unl
(ppm)
0
0
0
1.100

100
3.100
1.100

0

MMtaam
SoD Unl
(pprnl
3,100
2.200
3.100
1.100
5,800
1.200
asm
1.200
QUO
600

DmtUml
Ippml
0
0
0
3,300
1400
1400
1.100

1.100
1JOO

HlMtlillMl
Ippml
1.200


3.300
sjm
3,800
1.200
3JOO
1.100


Mmtanm
iHlMffalP •>•!•!
ftngiml
0
1
1
5
0
B
10
B
11
0

MMknni
(mBlMl
22
22
22
B
0
13
11
11
11
10

AeMtflfiunt CoaM
HP = High Print Abatement
LP • Low Print Abatement
H8 - High Sell Abatement
L8 . Lew Sell Abatement
RO - Recurrent Dual Abatement
HP/H8 - High Paint. High Sell Abatement!
HP/18 - High Print. Lew Sell Abatementi
LP/HS n Lew Print, High Sell Abatementi
LP/LS n Lew Paint. Lew Sell Abatement.
NR D B Nonrecurrent Dual Abatement

-------
 Two-Media Hazard Levels

       In this section, decision rules based upon hazard levels for two-media plus the paint
 condition criterion are evaluated.  Under these circumstances, households have less leeway to
 optimize their abatement decisions than they did under the single-medium decision rules and
 much less than they did under the voluntary optimum.  To satisfy recommendations based upon
 a two-media decision rule, such as the case where the soil hazard level is 2,300 ppm and the
 paint hazard level is an XRF of 20, it is assumed that any homeowner whose home exceeds
 either one of these thresholds would undertake the best abatement that makes it possible to go
 below both thresholds, as well as to meet the paint condition recommendation. In Exhibits 6-12
 and 6-13, the results for the best cases of the three different combinations (soil/dust, soil/paint,
 dust/paint) are presented.  The best cases are defined as the combinations having the highest net
 benefits.

       As was the case under the  single-medium decision rule, defining a hazard level for dust
 appears to be critical.  The two combinations based upon a dust hazard level of 1200 ppm (soil
 = 2300 ppm and dust = 1200 ppm; dust = 1200 ppm and paint = 20 (XRF)) have the highest
 net benefits. As shown in Exhibit  6-12, the net benefits are over $3 billion. The two dust-based
 decision  rules would induce  abatement in 15.7 to  16.2 million homes and  generate $33.0 to
 $34.9 billion in benefits.  In  contrast, the decision rule combining soil and paint hazard levels
 (soil  =  2,300  ppm and paint = 20 mg/cmj) has much lower benefits  ($11 billion) and,
 accordingly, negative net benefits (-$17.4 billion).

       The two rules based upon dust are approximately as accurate as the single-medium dust
 hazard level was in inducing abatements leading to positive net benefits.  The percentage of
 abatements  having negative net benefits is  about 47% for the soil/dust combination or the
 dust/paint combination. As shown in Exhibit 6-13,  the effectiveness of these two combinations
 stems from  their being able  to exploit nonrecurrent dust abatement, which is  not a feasible
 alternative when the hazard levels are based upon soil  and paint.

       For all three combinations, the paint condition criterion creates a tremendous burden.
 This outcome is illustrated for the  soil and dust combination, which has the highest net benefits
 among all of the two-media  decision rules.  Exhibit 6-14 paints a picture similar to the one
 already shown for dust in Exhibit 6-11.  Certain abatements never have positive net benefits (the
 combination of high-end paint and low-end  soil abatements and of low-end paint and high-end
 soil abatements), one form of abatement always generates positive net benefits (high-end soil),
 and some abatements generate positive net benefits for some homes and negative net benefits for
 others (high-end paint,low-end paint, low-end soil,  recurrent dust, low-end paint and low-end
 soil, and  nonrecurrent dust). Most notable among the latter are the homes where  high-end paint
 abatement has been induced.  The overwhelming majority of these  (97%) have negative net
 benefits.

      The biggest difference between the single-medium rule  based upon dust and the two-
 media rule based upon  soil and dust is that the two-media rule induces nearly half of a million
 homes to undertake low-end soil abatement that results in negative net benefits. This difference
 can be construed  as the price to pay for specifying a  two-media rather than a single-medium
 decision rule.

Abt Associates, Inc.                            6-21                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                                                                Exhibit 6-12

                                                          Banoflt-Coit Rnult* for Two Madia HIM Condition DeoMon Rule*
                                       (ppml
Img/etn'l
  Abatement
ReuoiHiiended
                                                                                                     (Eidualve of
                                                                                                    TeaOng Coote)
                                                                                                                     Coote
                                                                                                                                                 11000*1
                                                                                                                                                                 •DI HOOOal
                                                                           34.920
           Condition
                               2.300
                                                 20
                                                          Yes
                                                                           11.249
                                                                                           31,903
                                                                                                           3.017
                                                                                                                      24,346
                                                                                                                                    121.3291
                                                                                           29.699
                                                                                                          117.4401
                                      1.200
                                                 20
                                                                                                                      14.992
                                                                           33.009
                                                                                           29.991
                                                                                                           3.017
                                                                                                                      24.346
                                                                                                                                    132,422)
                                                                                                                                    121.3291
                                                                                                                                                    16.197
                                                                                                                                                                     7.683
                                                                                                                                                     8.169
                                                                                                                        7.2BB
                                                                                                                                                    16,702
                                                                                                                                                                     7.216
Candidate hazard lavah examined ranged up to 3000 ppm for toil. 2000 ppm for dint, and 22 mg/em* for paint.

-------
                                                                                                Exhibit 6 • 13
                                                                    Distribution of Abatamant Choice, for Two Madia Plua ConoWon Dadalon Rulaa

Condition
Ippml
2,300
2.300
•
Dint
Ippml
1.200
-
1.200
Paint
lmg/om'|
-
20
20
NonlntaMt Point
Abatamant

Yoi
Yai
Yai

HP
4.180
4.220
4.246

LP
2.672
2.755
2.770
Numbar of Homaa Abated by Abatamant Typa |1000a|
H8
74
0
74
L8
1.006
1.006
411
RO
270
0
270
HP/H8
0
0
0
HP/18
114
114
114
LP/H8
18
0
18
LP/L8
74
74
10
NRD
7.777
0
7.777
Total
10.197
8.109
16.702
Candidate hazard lovah examined ranged up to 3000 ppm for aoil. 2000 ppm for dual, and 22 mg/cm> for paint.
Abatamant Code.
HP - High Paint Abatamant
LP = Low Paint Abatamant
HS = High Soil Abatamant
LS = Low Soil Abatamant
RD = Recurrent Du.t Abatamant
HP/HS - High Paint. High Soil Abatement.
HP/IS = High Paint. Low Soil Abatement.
LP/HS = Low Paint. High Soil Abatement.
UP/IS • Low Paint. Low Soil Abatement.
NR 0  -  Nonrecurrent Dual Abatamant

-------
                                                                                              Exhfclte  14
                                                                             Two Modta Haurd Unit: Soil - 2100. Oust - 1200
Abottnont

In








Told
StatogT
Sobctod

HP
IP
MS
IS
RO
HP/IS
LPIHS
LP/LS
NRO

BoiMlHo
II rallUonil

5.301
1,360
290
3.724
885
564
65
260
22.472
34.920
Com
llmlllbu)

20.260
3.387
272
3.475
979
943
87
350
2.150
31.903
Not Bono! Hi
flminioml

114.960)
12.0271
18
249
1921
0791
1221
1911
20.322
1.017
IIOOO'i)

4.186
2.672
74
1.006
276
114
IB
74
7.777
16.196
Proportion
ol
AbitmontB

2534%
16.50%
0.46%
6.21%
1.71%
0.70%
0.11%
046%
48.02%

Abotomonn
Whh Mogothn
Hot Bonolho
liomroi
0
4.053
1469
0
469
202
114
IB
59
200
7.583
Minimum
IndMdnl
•olBonolho
W
0
0.6901
B.557I
S33
02281
0.529
18.514)
0.8011
14.0011
11301

Mixknom
todMdtMl
Hit MMiM
i»i
0
2.629
7.142
533
8.843
1.694
12.466)
11.6891
2J56
13.126

SoOtmol
Ippml
0
0
0
1.100
3,000
100
3.100
1.100
3.100
0

BollUwl
Ippml

2.200
2,200
1.100

1.200
8.800
1.200
8.600
600

Mmknn
DatlMtl
Ippml
0
0
0

1.100
1.400
1.100
2.500
1.100


DHltml
Ippml
1.200

5.800
3.300
5,800

1.200
3,300
1.200
5,900

Mmknam
htntn Mill
(mpjiml
0
1
1
S
0
6
10
5
10
0

Mixknam
hfnfat Pitnf
tagfem1)
22
22
22
5
11
13
11
11
11
10

Abatement Coda
HP - High Pclnl Abatement
IP . Low Mm AbMement
HS = High Sail Abatement
L6 = Low Soil Abatement
RD a Recurrent Out! Abatement
HP/HS • High Paint. High Soil Abalomonti
HP/16 • High Paint. Low Soil Abatements
LP/HS o Low Paint. High Soil Abatemenn
IP/18 n Low Paint. Low Soil Abatements
MR 0 «• Nonrocurrant Dual Abatement

-------
 Three-Media Hazard Levels

       Exhibit 6-15 shows the benefit-cost results for the combination of three-media hazard
 levels generating the highest net benefits (soil = 2300 ppm; dust = 1200 ppm; paint = 20
 mg/cm2). Adding one more dimension to the decision rule does not change the optimal hazard
 levels for soil, paint, or dust observed under the single-medium and two-media decision rules.
 It does however change the net benefits, lowering them slightly since homeowners have one
 more constraint on their decisions. The net benefits for the 2300/1200/20 rule are positive ($2.7
 billion) but slightly smaller than those of the single-medium and two-media decision rules.  Of
 the 16.3 million abatements  induced by these hazard levels, about 47%  lead to negative net
 benefits.  The major difference between the abatements induced by this decision rule and those
 induced by the single-medium  and the two-media decision rules is that more high-end paint,
 more low-end soil, and more low-end paint/low-end soil abatements are conducted.

 6.2.3  Other Decision Rules to Consider

       Among the  set of decision rules  that specify hazard levels, a rule based upon a dust
 hazard level of 1200 ppm and a paint condition criterion generates the highest net benefits ($3.3
 billion). It is important to note that, while this decision rule generates the highest net benefits,
 other soil, dust, and paint hazard levels can generate net benefits of lower but similar magnitude.
 Exhibit 6-16  shows other top combinations of different hazard levels.  They each generate net
 benefits within $2.2 billion of the highest net benefits achievable under a decision rule based
 upon dust equal to 1200 ppm. This expanded set of alternatives does not offer hazard levels for
 dust that are lower nor are there any two-media or three-media decision rules that are more
 stringent,  with one exception.   A two-media decision rule based upon a soil hazard level of
 2200 ppm and a dust hazard level of 1200 generates net benefits of $1.4 billion.

       These and other alternatives may also be contenders for an optimal set of soil and dust
 hazard levels if factors not yet encompassed in the current analysis are weighed in EPA's
 decisionmaking. One such possibility is  to choose the set of hazard levels that keeps the risk
 at an individual home of exceeding a blood lead concentration of IS  ug/dl below 5%. This can
 be achieved with a  hazard level of 500 ppm for soil and one of 400 ppm  for dust, in addition
 to the paint condition criterion.  As shown in Exhibit 6-17, these hazard levels have a net benefit
 of minus $18.8 billion.

       All of the above decision rules considered so far, including the voluntary optimum, are
 predicated upon testing homes.  With this information, abatement decisions can be based upon
 the circumstances of the homes, which offers the possibility of finding the best abatement for
 each home and as  a result, increasing the net benefits of abatement.   An altogether different
 approach would be to apply a given type of abatement to all homes, without conducting any
 prior tests. Clearly, under this approach, some homes would be abated when abatement was not
 appropriate, resulting in negative net benefits, but this is also the case for all of the decision
 rules besides  the voluntary optimum.  The central issue is whether these kinds of errors would
 be offset by savings in testing costs. The results for the voluntary optimum suggest one means
 for implementing such an approach in a way that increases overall net benefits.
Abt Associates. Inc.                           6-25                        Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                                                                              Exhibit 8-IS
                                                                     Thni Midli Hizard Lowlo: Soil - 2300. Dint - 1200. Interior Point - 20


Yn








retil
Stotogy
Sibctid

HP
IP
H8
18
RD
HPIL8
WHS
IP/IS
NRD

Bimllti
ItmlWonil

5.360
1.365
290
3.724
885
564
65
260
22.472
34.984
Coin
(IniDlonol

20.555
3.430
272
3.475
970
943
87
350
2.150
32.248
Hit BIIMI M
UmllNonol

115.1961
12.0731
18
249
1921
0791
122)
Oil
20.322
2.718
ol Abolonranto
IIOOO-o)

4.246
2.712
74
1,006
276
114
18
74
7.777
16.297
Proportion
ol
Abittmonti

26.06%
16.64%
045%
6.17%
1.70%
0.70%
0.11%
0.46%
47.72%

WllhNogilrn
Not BomlHo
IIOOO'o)

4.114
2.508
0
469
202
114
18
58
200
7.683
Minimum
MMdnl
Mot BomlHo
1*1
0

0.5571

12.2281
13.5261
B.514I
13.9011
14.0011
11301

MoKimra
InHluliliioil
UWIVIuUII
HotBonolHo
1*1
0
2.629
7.142
533
8.843
1.694
12.466)
11.689)
23SB
13.126

Minimum
Sod Ural
to*)
0
0
0
1.100

100
3,100
1.100
3,100
0

Mixknnm
Sod Ural
Ippml
2JOO
1200
2.200
1.100
8.800
1.200
8,800
1.200

600

Boat 1ml
Ippa)
0
0
0
3.300
1.100
1,400
1.100
2,500
1.100
1.300

Dot Loral
Ippml
1,200


1300
5.800
3,600
1.200
3,300
1.200


Mlnknn
hrtorior Point
IHIJtnvi
0
1
1
5
0
6
10
5
10
0

kMwbrPiuit
(mihni
20
22
22
S
11
13
H
11
11
10

Abatement Cooea
HP = High PMnt Abatement
LP - Low Print Abatement
HS = High Soil AbMariMnt
L8 = Lew Soil Abatement
RD = Reeuiient Du>t Abatement
HP/HS n High Palm. High Soil Abatement
HP/LS - High Palm, Lew Sell Abatamenio
LP/HS o Lew Palm. High Soil Abatement
LP/LS » Low Paint, Lew Soil Abalamenla
NH D • Nonteeurrant Dual Abatement

-------
             Exhibit 6-16
Near Contenders for Highest Net Benefits
Soil
(ppm)
—
—
—
3.000
2.900
2.800
2,700
2,600
2,500
2,400
2,300
3,000
3,000
2,900
2,900
2,800
2,800
2,700
2,700
2,600
2,600
2,500
2.500
2.400
2.400
2.300
2.300
—
—
—
—
3.000
2.900
2.800
2,700
2,600
2,500
2.400
2,300
2.900
2.800
2.700
Dust
(ppm)
1.200
1.200
1,200
1,200
1.200
1,200
1.200
1,200
1.200
1,200
1,200
1,200
1,200
1,200
1,200
1.200
1,200
1,200
1.200
1.200
1,200
1,200
1,200
1,200
1.200
1,200
1,200
1.300
1.400
1.300
1.300
1,300
1,300
1,300
1,300
1,300
1.300
1,300
1.300
1,400
1,400
1,400
Paint
(mg/cmx
—
21
20
—
—
—
—
—
—
—
—
21
20
21
20
21
20
21
20
21
20
21
20
21
20
21
20
—
—
21
20
—
—
—
—
—
—
—
—
—
—
—
Total
Benefits
(* millions
32,945
33,009
33.009
34,920
34,920
34.920
34.920
34,920
34,920
34,920
34.920
34,984
34,984
34,984
34,984
34,984
34,984
34,984
34,984
34,984
34,984
34,984
34,984
34,984
34,984
34,984
34,984
31,413
29,669
31,477
31.477
33,389
33,389
33,389
33,389
33,389
33.389
33.389
33,389
32,847
32,847
32.847
Total
Costs
($ millions)
29,646
29,991
29.991
31,903
31,903
31,903
31,903
31.903
31,903
31,903
31,903
32,248
32,248
32.248
32,248
32,248
32.248
32,248
32,248
32.248
32.248
32,248
32,248
32,248
32,248
32,248
32,248
29,128
27,557
29,473
29.473
31.385
31.385
31,385
31,385
31.385
31.385
31.385
31.385
30,917
30,917
30,917
Net Benefits
(* millions)
3,299
3.017
3,017
3,017
3,017
3,017
3,017
3,017
3,017
3.017
3,017
2,736
2.736
2.736
2,736
2,736
2.736
2.736
2.736
2.736
2,736
2.736
2,736
2,736
2,736
2.736
2.736
2.285
2.112
2,004
2,004
2,004
2,004
2,004
2,004
2,004
2,004
2,004
2,004
1,929
1,929
1.929
Total Number
of Abatement!
(1000's)
15,602
15,702
15,702
16,197
16,197
16,197
16,197
16.197
16,197
16,197
16,197
16,297
16.297
16,297
16,297
16,297
16.297
16.297
16.297
16.297
16.297
16.297
16.297
16,297
16.297
16,297
16,297
14,654
13,954
14,754
14.754
15,249
15.249
15,249
15,249
15.249
1 5.249
15,249
15,249
14,869
14,869
14.869
Abatements
With Negative
Net Benefits
(1000's)
7.114
7.215
7.215
7,583
7,583
7,583
7,583
7,583
7,583
7,583
7,583
7,684
7,684
7,684
7,684
7,684
7,684
7,684
7,684
7,684
7,684
7,684
7,684
7,684
7.684
7,684
7,684
7,031
6,803
7,132
7.132
7.500
7.500
7.500
7,500
7,500
7,500
7,500
7.500
7.272
7.272
7,272

-------
             Exhibit 6-16
Near Contenders for Highest Net Benefits
Soil
(ppm)
2,600
2,500
2,400
2,300
—
—
3,000
3,000
3,000
2,900
2,900
2,800
2,800
2.700
2,700
2,600
2,600
2,500
2,500
2,400
2.400
2,300
2,300
2,900
2,900
2,800
2,800
2,700
2,700
2,600
2,600
2,500
2,500
2,400
2,400
2,300
2,300
—
3.000
3.000
2,900
2.800
Dust

-------
             Exhibit 6-16
Near Contenders for Highest Net Benefits
Soil
(ppm)
2.700
2.600
2.500
2.400
2,300
2.200
—
—
3.000
—
2.800
2.800
2.700
2,700
2.600
2,600
2,500
2,500
2,400
2,400
2,300
2,300
Dust
(ppm)
1,500
1,500
1.500
1.500
1,500
1.200
.500
.500
,500
,600
,500
,500
.500
.500
.500
,500
,500
,500
,500
,500
,500
,500
D^IM*
rBini
(mg/cm1
—
—
—
—
—
—
21
20
—
—
21
20
21
20
21
20
21
20
21
20
21
20
Total
Benefits
(ft millions)
32.024
32,024
32.024
32,024
32,024
38,380
28.910
28.910
30.821
28,342
32,088
32,088
32,088
32,088
32.088
32,088
32,088
32,088
32.088
32.088
32,088
32,088
Total
Costs
(ft millions)
30,652
30,652
30.652
30,652
30,652
37,029
27,637
27,637
29,548
27,218
30,997
30,997
30,997
30,997
30,997
30,997
30,997
30,997
30,997
30.997
30,997
30,997
Net Benefits
(ft millions)
.372
.372
.372
.372
.372
.350
.273
.273
1.273
1.124
.090
.090
.090
,090
,090
,090
.090
,090
.090
1.090
1,090
1,090
Total Number
of Abatements
(1000's)
14.479
14,479
14,479
14,479
14,479
18,267
13,665
13,665
14,159
13,351
14.579
14.579
14.579
14,579
14,579
14,579
14,579
14,579
14,579
14,579
14,579
14.579
Abatements
With Negative
Net Benefits
(1000's)
7.231
7.231
7.231
7.231
7.231
9,653
6.862
6,862
7,231
6,762
7.331
7.331
7.331
7.331
7,331
7.331
7.331
7,331
7,331
7,331
7,331
7,331

-------
                      Exhibit 6-17
Alternative Hazard Levels Based Upon Soil
500. Dust = 400
Soil
(ppm)
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
500
Dust
(ppm)
400
400
400
400
400
400
400
400
400
400
400
400
400
400
400
400
400
400
400
400
400
400
400
Paint
(XRF)
—
21
20
19
18
17
16
15
14
13
12
11
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
Total
Benefits
(* millions)
66,688
66,752
66,752
66,711
66.711
66.711
66,711
66,71 1
66,711
66.711
66,737
66,770
66,770
66.816
67,228
67,438
67.573
67,537
67,623
67.705
68,186
68,993
73,234
Total
Costs
(» millions)
85.445
85,790
85.790
86.910
86,910
86.910
86,910
86,910
86,910
86,910
86,998
87,229
87,229
87,481
88,478
89.138
90,248
91,457
91,703
92,577
96,479
105,526
146,212
Net Benefits
(« millions)
(18.757)
(19,038)
(19,038)
(20,199)
(20.199)
(20,199)
(20,199)
(20.199)
(20,199)
(20.199)
(20,261)
(20,460)
(20,460)
(20,665)
(21,250)
(21,699)
(22,675)
(23,920)
(24,079)
(24,871)
(28,293)
(36,533)
(72.978)
Total Number
of Abatements
(1000's)
45.563
45,664
45,664
45,728
45,728
45,728
45,728
45,728
45.728
45.728
45,728
45,728
45,728
45,728
45,728
45,797
46,049
46,049
46,049
46,304
47,099
49,537
59,039
Abatements
With Negative
Net Benefits
(1000's)
21,584
21.685
21,685
21.749
21,749
21.749
21,749
21,749
21,749
21,749
21,749
21,749
21,749
21,749
21,749
21,818
22,070
22,070
22,191
22,446
23,241
25,679
36,283

-------
              Most of the abatements chosen under the voluntary optimum are nonrecurrent dust
 abatements (99%) (Exhibit 6-2). Since the voluntary optimum decision rule presumes testing
 prior to the abatement choice, this new approach must impose additional abatements costing no
 more than the avoided testing costs ($24 billion) to improve on the overall net benefits of the
 voluntary optimum rule.  Given average discounted nonrecurrent dust abatement costs of $267
 and the finding that 62.2 million homeowners chose not to abate under the voluntary optimum,
 the incremental cost of imposing nonrecurrent dust abatement on all homes is $16.6 billion.
 Some of these homes would also accrue benefits (even though net benefits are negative). There
 would also be a small loss in benefits from those achieved under the voluntary optimum since
 the homes choosing low-end paint and low-end soil abatements are not given the choice under
 this rule.   A preliminary estimate suggests a net increase in benefits of about $2 billion.

        Adding this estimate to  the net costs avoided (equal to $24.2 billion  in testing costs
 avoided minus $16.6 billion in additional abatement costs), there is a net gain  of $9.6 billion.
 In  other words,  with testing costs, the voluntary optimum decision rule  generates net benefits
 of  $10  billion while this hybrid rule, based strictly upon nonrecurrent dust abatement, would
 generate net benefits of approximately $20 billion.  These higher net benefits can be achieved
 through this uniform approach even though the percentage of homes with negative net benefits
 (58%)  is  higher than that of the voluntary optimum (0%) or those of the best of the other
 decision rules (about 47%).

       It  is unclear, however,  how  reliable this particular abatement approach  based upon
 nonrecurrent dust abatement is since it relies exclusively on one, substantial cleaning of every
 home involved.  Nonetheless, the improvements this approach offers underscores the important
 role that testing costs may play in the abatement choices initiated by hazard  levels set under
 Section 403.  It also suggests that there may be ways to construct guidance to the public which
 takes testing costs into account.

       In  sum, further investigation of factors not fully considered in this analysis may reveal
 additional opportunities for creating decision rules to  address outstanding EPA concerns, and
 possibly, to create higher net benefits.

 6.3   SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION

       Exhibits 6-18 and 6-19 summarize  the benefit-cost information presented above for all
 five sets of decision rules.  The  final comparison of these results integrates information on the
 testing  costs necessary to implement each of these  decision rules.  This information was
 presented in the discussion of the overall net benefits of the voluntary optimum decision rule but
 not for  the other decision rules.  Since there  is variation  in the tests  that are  required for
 different decision rules (testing soil or dust for lead content or testing paint for condition or lead
 content), the testing costs that are prerequisite to abatement decisions also vary.

      The inclusion of testing costs does not alter the ranking of nine decision rules considered
 here. The voluntary optimum still has the highest net benefits ($10 billion).   All subsequent
decision rules have  negative net benefits.  The top four among these are based upon a single
medium (dust=1200),  two  media  (soil=2300/dust=1200,  dust=1200/paint=20), and three
media (soil=2300/dust=12007 paint=20).  The overall net benefits of any of these decision

Abt Associates, Inc.                           6-31                        Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 rules is approximately minus $21 billion. The three lowest-ranking decision rules all have in
 common that they are based in some way upon a paint hazard level.  The qualitative hazard level
 based upon paint condition criterion ranks seventh, the two-media rule based upon soil and paint
 ranks eighth, and the single-medium hazard level based upon paint alone ranks ninth.  These
 outcomes and the finding of significant negative net benefits associated with paint abatement
 highlight the potentially significant influence of the assumptions made regarding the effectiveness
 and cost of paint abatement.

        Another notable difference between the top-ranked decision rule and the next four is the
 number of homes abated. The decision rules based upon qualitative or quantitative hazard levels
 induce no more than 16.3 million abatements, of which 7 to 8 million have negative net benefits.
 The voluntary optimum leads to nearly three times as many abatements - more than 45 million
 abatements. None entails negative net benefits.  This finding raises the possibility that better
 decision rules could be created that are both implementable, which  is the advantage of the
 decision rules based upon hazard levels,  and that lead to positive and substantial net benefits,
 which the voluntary optimum does. Since the information bases assumed for the first group and
 for the voluntary optimum differ substantially, it appears that creating  a  better means  for
 conveying useful information to guide homeowners' abatement decisions could be a productive
 route for improving upon the decision rules investigated here.  This may be an important point
 of departure for  subsequent investigations.

        A more immediate point of departure for investigation is to put the  current analysis into
 perspective by considering the sensitivity of the results to various critical  assumptions.  Some
 conclusions from this analysis have been strongly influenced by certain parameters used in the
 current analysis.   For example, the  influence of assumptions regarding the cost and extent of
 abatement of non-intact paint on net benefits has been highlighted.  Alternative assumptions
 about these unit costs and those of other abatements could affect the net benefits and the number
 of abatements  for each decision rule.  The discount  rate applied  to  benefits and costs also
 appears to be  particularly influential.  The  sensitivity of  the benefits and costs of different
 decision rules to  these and other parameters is investigated in the next  chapter.
Abt Associates. Inc.                           6-32                       Draft, January 10. 1994

-------
                                                                                       Exhibits- 18

                                                                    Benefit-Cost Results (or Five Alternative Decision Rides

1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
Decision Rules
Voluntary Optimum
Paint Condition Only
Single Medium Plus
Condition
2-Media Plus
Condition
3a.
3b.
3c.
4a.
4b.
4c.
3-Media Plus Condition
Soil
(ppm)
-
-
2,300
•
•
2,300
2,300
•
2,300
Dust
(ppm)
-
-
-
1,200
•
1,200
-
1,200
1,200
Paint
mg/cm1
-
-
-
•
20
-
20
20
20
Nonintact Paint
Abatement
Recommended
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Benefits
($ million)
48,190
7,319
11,186
32,945
7,383
34,920
1 1 ,249
33,009
34,984
Abatement
Costs
($ million)
13,896
24,668
28,345
29,646
25,014
31.903
28,689
29,992
32,248
Net Benefits
(Exclusive of
Testing Costs)
($ million)
34,294
(17,349)
(17.159)
3,299
(17.631)
3.017
(17.440)
3,017
2,736
Testing
Costs
($ million)
24,222
14,987
24,222
24,227
14.906
24,227
24,222
24,227
24,231
Net Benefits
(Including
Testing Costs)
($ million)
10.072
(32.336)
(41,381)
(20,928)
(32.537)
(21.210)
(41.662)
(21.210)
(21,495)
Total Number
of Abatements
(1000s)
45.165
7.063
8.069
16.602
7,164
16.197
8,170
16,702
16,297
Number of
Abatemanta with
Negative Nat
Banafita (lOOOi)
0
6.686
7,164
7.114
6,786
7,683
7.266
7.216
7,684
Candidate hazard levels examined ranged up to 3000 ppm for soil, 2000 ppm for dust, and 22 mg/cm1 for paint.
Voluntary Optimum:

Paint Condition Only:


Single Medium:


2-Media:


3-Media:
 Each home selects ebatement (or no abatement) that has the highest net benefits

 Abatement is recommended for homes with more than five square feet of lead-based paint in nonintaet condition, regardless of XRF level or net
benefits. Homeowners choose the paint ebatement method thet generates the highest net benefits.

 Within the full range of individual soil,  dust, end paint hazard levels that could be set as a threshold for action, with no constraints placed on the other
two medie, the levels specified in  the table maximize net benefits.

 Within the full range of individual soil,  dual, and paint hazard level combinations that could be set as a threshold for action, with no restriction on the
other medium, the levels specified in the table maximize net benefite.

 Within the full range of individual soil,  dust, end paint hazard level combinations that could be set as a threshold for action, the levels specified in the
table maximizes net benefits.

-------
                                                                                Exhibit 6-19

                                                        Distribution of Abatement Choices for Five Alternative Decision Rules

'•







Condition
2-Media Plus
Condition

3a.
3b.
3c.
4a.
4b.
4c.

(ppm)

-
2.300
•
•
2.300
2.300
•
2,300
(ppm)

-
-
1.200
•
1.200
•
1.200
1.200
(mg/cm*

-
•
-
20

20
20
20
Abatement
Recommended


Yee
Yes




Yes

HP

4.160
4.160
4,186
4.221
4.186
4.221
4.247
4,247

LP

2,774
2,716
2,731
2,814
2,672
2,756
2,770
2,712
Number of Homes Abated by Abatement Type (1000s)
HS

0
0
74
0
74
0
74
74
LS

0
1,006
411
0
1.006
1.006
411
1,006
RD
0
0
0
276
0
276
0
276
276
HP/HS
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
HP/LS
0
114
114
114
114
114
114
114
114
LP/HS
0
0
0
18
0
18
0
18
18
LP/LS
0
16
74
16
16
74
74
16
74
NRD
44.567
0
0
7.777
0
7.777
0
7.777
7,777
Total
46.166
7,063
8.069
16,602
7,164
16,197
8.170
16.702
i 6,297
Candidate hazard levels examined ranged up to 3000 ppm for soil, 2000 ppm for dust, and 22 mg/cm1 for paint.
Abatement Codes
HP = High Paint Abatement
LP  = Low Paint Abatement
HS = High Soil Abatement
LS  = Low Soil Abatement
RD = Recurrent Dust Abatement
Voluntary Optimum:

Paint Condition Only:


Single Medium:


2-Media:


3-Media:
                     HP/HS  = High Paint, High Soil Abatements
                     HP/LS = High Paint. Low Soil Abatements
                     LP/HS = Low Paint. High Soil Abatements
                     LP/LS = Low Paint, Low Soil Abatements
                     NR D = Nonrecurrent Dust Abatement

  Each home selects abatement (or no abatement) that has the highest net benefits
 Abatement is recommended for homes with more than five square feet of lead-based paint in nonintaet condition, regardless of XRF level or net
benefits. Homeowners choose the paint abatement method that generates the highest net benefits.

 Within the full range of individual soil, dust, and paint hazard levels that could be set as a threshold for action, with no constraints placed on the other
two media, the levels specified in the table maximize net benefits.

 Within the full range of individual soil, dust, and paint hazard level combinations that could be set as a threshold for action, with no restriction on the
other medium, the levels specified in the table maximize net benefits.

 Within the full  range of individual soil, dust, and paint hazard level combinations that could be set as a threshold for action, the levels specified In the
table maximizes net benefits.

-------
                             7. SENSITIVITY ANALYSES
       Any modelling to support environmental policy analysis depends on making judgments
 in how to depict human behavior, environmental circumstances, and their interactions. These
 judgments draw variously on the analysts' expertise, existing knowledge about the problem at
 hand, the advice of relevant specialists, and conclusions drawn from available data and studies.
 One objective in combining insights gleaned from these sources is to fill the substantial gaps in
 current understanding in a way that provides a "reasonable" characterization of the problem at
 hand.   Still,  what constitutes  a reasonable  characterization may  not be  the definitive
 characterization. It may apply to a large number but not all circumstances in the real world.
 Or,  it could be based on a set of assumptions about which even the best-informed analysts would
 disagree. More than likely, it will be subject to both conditions.

       This chapter considers the influence of alternative assumptions on the benefits and cost
 of lead  abatement  in residential  settings.   The results are presented as sensitivity analyses
 because they represent alternative specifications to the model used to calculate benefits and costs
 rather than radical reconfigurations of the modelling framework.  The aim is to determine
 whether changing a relatively  small number of parameters but in  a credible way can lead  to
 substantial changes in the policy-relevant outcomes.

       The number of parameters considered in this chapter is limited to a few selected items.
 In part, this selection is due to model refinement which has already taken place.  Yesterday's
 "sensitivity analyses" became today's model enhancements, which  were formally incorporated
 into the framework. The selection also stems from the desire to focus on parameters that had
 a  significant likelihood of  influencing the  policy-relevant outcomes.  By no means  are the
 parameters examined here  the ones with the  greatest potential for changing these outcomes.
 Other modelling assumptions have greater potential but they often represent more controversial
 assumptions.  Finally, the selection derives from a limit on the number of sensitivity analyses
 that  can be generated.  The binding constraint is not so much a limit on the number of modelling
 iterations that can be run since with faster computing power, immense numbers of modelling
 runs can be undertaken with changes in assumptions  engineered from one iteration to the next.
 The  real  limit is on the ability to organize the results from a large number of iterations in a way
 that  lends itself to reliable quality assurance, interpretation, and presentation.

       In the next section, a brief overview of potential sensitivity analyses is provided.  In the
 three subsequent sections,  sensitivity  analyses based upon alternative cost and  discounting
 assumptions are presented.

 7.1    POTENTIAL SENSITIVITY ANALYSES

       Two sets of parameters will be discussed. The first set includes parameters tied primarily
 to cost  calculations and the second,  ones that are relevant  to benefit calculations.   This
 classification masks what  may be the ultimate factor determining whether they should be
 evaluated. It is the effect of changing these parameters on the optimal hazard levels of different
 decision  rules and the net benefits of these different decision rules which is one of the most

Abt Associates, Inc.                           7-1                        Draft. January  10, 1994

-------
 policy-relevant outcomes that can come from any sensitivity analyses.  However, presenting the
 sensitivity analyses in this manner may give clearer indications on where these assumptions fit
 into the model.

        For the cost calculations, two general sets of assumptions stand out as candidates for
 sensitivity analyses. The first set encompasses assumptions regarding the unit costs of abatement
 of soil, dust, or paint.  For soil abatement, possible variations include different assumptions
 regarding the nature of abatement, the level at which soil is considered hazardous, and the costs
 of transportation and disposal.  For dust abatement, unit costs currently depend on the type and
 frequency of different levels of abatement.  For paint abatement, costs are highly dependent on
 the condition and amount of lead paint present, among other factors. Some of these variations
 may be captured explicitly or  implicitly in the range of unit cost estimates.   The results  in
 previous chapters were based upon a set of "medium" cost estimates.  This chapter considers
 the impacts that using low and high unit cost estimates have on the benefits and costs of different
 decision  rules and their optimal hazard levels.  The second set  of assumptions relates to
 assumptions about testing costs.  The numbers of soil, dust, and paint samples and the numbers
 of households tested are critical components of  the unit and aggregate costs, respectively.
 Furthermore, the costs per sample could have considerable regional variation.

        The benefit  calculations  depend on a wide array of assumptions that could be subjected
 to  sensitivity analyses.  Because there are so many potentially influential assumptions, it  is
 important to narrow the set of potential candidates.  Determining which assumptions are the best
 candidates for sensitivity analysis and how the given assumptions should be altered complicates
 the task of conducting  the sensitivity analysis. For example, the effectiveness and durability of
 various forms of abatement have not been thoroughly quantified by studies to date but for the
 purposes of calculating benefits it is necessary to  quantify them explicitly.  It  is possible that
 there are alternate, credible assumptions besides those currently made in this analysis that would
 alter the policy-relevant outcomes.

       Some of the possible variations in assumptions are substantial  enough to constitute major
 model revisions rather than sensitivity analyses. For example, the main analysis did not include
 benefits for children who already exist at the beginning of the time period covered by the model.
 Although benefits for  these children can be estimated,  incorporating  the influence of  these
 benefits on abatements  decisions is more difficult and will require a significant adjustment to the
 model. The potential benefits to adults from avoided high blood pressure effects from exposure
 to lead have not been included in the model either.  If exposures for adults to lead contamination
 from residential soil, dust, or paint are significant, these benefits could have a substantial impact
 on  policy-relevant  outcomes  of the  analysis, including  the timing,  number,  and types of
 abatements and most important,  the optimal hazard levels for different decision rules. Like the
 benefits for existing children, changing the  model to make abatement decisions responsive to
 adult exposures will  require a significant  adjustments  since abatement will no  longer be
 exclusively induced by births.  A further obstacle to incorporating such benefits is  that the
 evidence supporting their validity is very limited.

       Questions  have also been raised about the variation in benefits  that  derives  from
 differences in exposures from lead contamination in bare versus covered  soil. Exposure  to the
 former entails higher ingestion  of lead than exposure to the latter, under  otherwise similar

Abt Associates, Inc.                           7-2                       Draft. January 10, 1994

-------
 circumstances, which means that bare soil could have a lower optimal hazard level than covered
 soil.  The magnitude of these differences is unknown and little information is available to
 suggest a conclusive resolution of this issue. Dealing with a related set of assumptions - soil and
 dust ingestion rates employed in the ffiUBK model - offers another target for sensitivity analyses
 but setting a new range for these values to address the bare/covered soil issue is almost an  ad
 hoc exercise.

        Because of the breadth of the potential changes implicit in varying these assumptions, to
 date a conservative approach has been taken toward what will be presented here.  As mentioned
 above, the first sensitivity analysis considers low and high unit cost estimates. The second
 sensitivity analysis focuses on changing one particular parameter of the analysis that has a large
 potential for affecting policy-relevant outcomes but is also relatively easy to implement. This
 parameter is the discount rate used to express the monetary  value of future  benefits and costs
 in contemporary terms. A rate of 7% was  used for the analysis presented in previous chapters.
 An alternate approach, which has been used by the Agency in some other regulatory analyses,
 involves a two-stage discounting procedure that employs both 3% and 7%.  Results using this
 procedure will be presented below. The third sensitivity analysis illustrates the kinds of effects
 that the potential benefits to adults and existing children could have on the benefit-cost analysis.
 For this exercise, the benefits estimated for newborn children were supplemented by estimates
 for adults and existing children but the  basis for abatement decisions - the imminent birth of a
 child - remains the  same.

 7.2    ALTERNATIVE COST ASSUMPTIONS

       The information on unit costs of abatement provided in Chapter 4 provides the basis for
 a  wide array of different cost assumptions.  For the abatement of one single medium,  three
 different estimates were  developed - a high  one, a low one, and a medium one.   Once the
 abatement of more than one medium is considered, the number of alternative cost combinations
 that could apply to a given home grows exponentially. With  the addition of one more medium
 to abate, the number of cost estimates increases from three to  nine. With the addition of a third
 medium, the number of cost estimates rises to twenty-seven.   If information on the likely
 frequency of these different cost combinations were available, these different cost combinations
 could be integrated explicitly in the abatement decisions of the homeowners, such as by having
 homeowners consider the expected  costs of high-end paint and  low-end soil abatement, rather
 than only the medium estimates. However, information on the distributions of abatement costs
 was considered too limited to allow approximating such distributions  reliably.

       One alternative  to trying to characterize the distributions of cost estimates in  their
 entirety is to look at the impact that the extreme values have  on the policy-relevant outcomes.
 On this basis, at least it would be feasible to establish boundaries on the possible benefit-cost
 results and the estimated optimal hazard levels.  While the low and high unit cost estimates
 presented  in  Chapter 4  are not the ultimate  minimum and  maximum values, they  were
 constructed to be representative of the lower and upper ranges of values observed in practice.
 As such, the low and high unit values  of Chapter 4  are probably appropriate for testing the
 boundaries of the benefit-cost analysis.
Abt Associates. Inc.                           7-3                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
        The sensitivity analyses for the high and low cost scenarios focuses on comparisons of
 the five alternative decision rules targeted in Chapter 6.  To facilitate these comparisons, tables
 were constructed for each scenario analogous to the ones presenting the benefit-cost results and
 the distribution of abatement choices in Chapter 6 (Exhibits 6-18 and 6-19).  Exhibits 7-1 and
 7-2 present these findings for the high cost scenario.  Exhibits 7-3 and 7-4 present those for the
 low cost scenario.

        For the high cost scenario, the most important rinding may be that the optimal hazard
 levels are exactly the same for most versions of the decision rules. As shown in Exhibit 7-1,
 for dust the optimal hazard level is still 1,200 ppm in  all  cases (single medium,  two-media,
 three-media). Furthermore, the decision rules with the highest net benefits are still those which
 involve setting a dust hazard level. For paint  the optimal level is still 20 mg/cm2. For soil, the
 optimal hazard level is still  2,300 ppm in the decision rules having the highest net benefits (three
 media, two media when combined with a dust hazard level) but is 3,000 ppm for decision rules
 which have markedly lower net benefits. In  all decision rules except the voluntary optimum,
 the net benefits are negative.  The net benefits for the voluntary optimum decline by 18% but
 the number of abatements declines more dramatically, by 27%, as shown in Exhibit 7-2.  The
 numbers of abatements induced by the other decision rules stay basically the same.  There are
 minor shirts away from the  more expensive abatements, such as high-end paint/low-end soil, but
 mainly the distributions of  abatements change little if at all.

       For the low cost scenario, the optimal levels for dust and paint again remain at the levels
 generated by the  main analysis (1,200 ppm for dust and 20 mg/cm2 for paint) but the optimal
 hazard level for soil is 35% lower.  As shown in Exhibit 7-3, the optimal hazard level for soil
 in all relevant decision rules is 1,500 ppm.  This appears to be the most significant difference
 in the results for the induced rules. Although the net benefits are substantially larger for all
 decision rules and positive (exclusive of testing costs) for most, the net benefits are still negative
 for the decision rules that had negative net benefits  in the main analysis (the paint condition rule,
 the single medium soil and paint decision  rules and the two-media rule combining soil and
 paint).  Notably  the number of abatements  having negative net benefits does not decline
 appreciably. In the case of the single-medium dust rule,  for example, the decline is only 10%.

       The  other  significant  differences  between the results  for the main  analysis and this
 sensitivity analysis are associated with the voluntary optimum. As shown in Exhibit 7-4, the
 number of abatements jumps from 45 million to almost 78 million.  As before, an overwhelming
 majority of these are nonrecurrent dust abatements (95 %). There is however a slight adjustment
 to the distribution with the addition of high-end soil abatements,  when  there had been none
 before, and with a six-fold increase in the number of low-end soil and low-end paint abatements.

       In conclusion, this bounding exercise indicates that findings regarding optimal dust and
 paint hazard levels may not  be affected by a better representation of the distribution of abatement
 costs.  Dramatic upward and downward revisions applied simultaneously to all abatements did
 not change the optimal hazard levels for dust  and  paint.  This does not however categorically
 rule out revisions in cost estimates which could affect the optimal dust and paint hazard levels.
 It is important to remember that the abatement  choices are the result of comparing all abatement
 choices allowed by a given  rule. If cost estimates for abatements to one medium in particular
 are significantly revised without changes to  the estimated abatement costs for other media, the

Abt Associates. Inc.                           7-4                       Draft, January 10,  1994

-------
optimal hazard level for that medium is likely to change.  Whether this is a rare possibility or
not is unknown.  Given current information it seems unlikely to occur with the estimated dust
abatement costs, given their significantly lower magnitudes, but it could affect the estimated
paint abatement costs, which already exhibit a very broad range.

       This sensitivity analysis has shown that the optimal soil hazard level could be susceptible
to changes in assumptions regarding the costs of abatement. While the optimal soil hazard level
held constant at 2,300 ppm for an upward revision in all abatement costs, it fell to 1,500 ppm
when all costs were lowered.  Although it has already been shown  in Chapter 6 that certain
small  changes in  the  hazard level for a  particular  medium  do  not  change net  benefits
significantly, in this case there is a significant change.  In the main analysis, the best  decision
rule,  given that the soil hazard  level is fixed  at 1,500 ppm, has negative net benefits (-$7
billion).1   When the soil hazard level is instead allowed to fluctuate, the best decision rule
involving soil is one having a soil hazard level of 2,300 ppm. This rule has positive net benefits
($3 billion).  Consequently, it appears that the evidence for setting a single hazard level for soil
is not clearcut.  Instead, a range from  1,500 to 2,300 ppm is supported by the model when
bounding cost assumptions are applied.
       The best decision rule when the soil hazard level is fixed at 1,500 ppm and the paint condition applies is
a two-media rule where the dust hazard level is 1,200 ppm.

Abt Associates, Inc.                            7-5                        Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                                                            Exhibit 7-1

                                              Benefit-Cost Results for Five Alternative Decision Rules. High Cost Scenario

I-

3.
4.
5.



Single Medium Plus
Condition
2-Media Plus
Condition

3a.
3b.
3c.
4a.
4b.
4c.
3-Medla Plus Condition
Sod
(ppml
-
-
3.000
-
-
2.300
3.000
-
2.300
Oust
Ippml
-
•
-
1.200
•
1.200
•
1.200
1.200
Paint
Img/cm'l
-
-
-
-
20
-
20
20
20
Nonbitaet Paint
Abatement
Recommended
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Benefits
I* mllDonl
43,122
6.991
9.983
32.604
7.055
34.907
10.047
32.668
34.970
Abatement
Costs
ItmODonl
15.008
30.135
34.239
37,166
30.662
40,820
34,666
37.592
41,246
Net Benefits
(Exclusive of
Tasting Costs)
28.114
(23.144)
(24,256)
(4.562)
(23,607)
(5,913)
(24,618)
(4,926)
(6,276)
Total Number
of Abatements
(1000s)
33.098
7,063
7.760
16,602
7,164
16,197
7,850
16,702
16,297
Number of
Abatements with
Negative Net

6,726
7,196
7,648
6.827
8,017
7,295
7,649

Candidate hazard levels examined ranged up to 3000 ppm for soil. 2000 ppm for dust, and 22 mg/cm* for paint.

Voluntary Optimum:             Each home selects abatement (or no abatement) that has the highest net benefits
Paint Condition Only:
Single Medium:
2-Media:
3-Media:
  Abatement Is recommended for homes with more than five square feet of lead-based paint In nonlntact condition, regardless of XRF level or net
benefits. Homeowners choose the paint abatement method that generates the highest net benefit*.

  Within the full range of individual soil, dust, and paint hazard levels that could be set as e threshold for action, with no constraints placed on the other
two media, the levels specified in the table maximize net benefits.

  Within the full range of individual soil, dust, and paint hazard level combinations that could be set as a threshold for action, with no restriction on the
other medium, the levels specified in the table maximize net benefits.

  Within the full range of Individual soil, dust, and paint hazard level combinations that could be set as a threshold for action, the levels specified In the
table maximizes net benefits.

-------
                                                                                          Exhibit 7-2

                                                       Distribution ol Abatement Choices for Five Alternative Decision Rules. High Cost Scenario


2.
3.
4.
5.

Voluntary Optimum
Paint Condition Only
Single Medium Plus
Condition
2-Media Plus
Condition

38.
3b.
3c.
4a.
4b.
4c.
3-Media Plus Condition
(ppml

-
3.000
-
-
2.300
3.000
-
2.300
Ippml

-
-
1.2OO
-
1.200
-
1.200
1.200
Paint
(mB/cm'l

•
-
-
20
-
20
20
20
Nonlntact Paint
Abatement
Recommended
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Number of Homes Abated by Abatement Type (1000s)
HP
0
4.249
4,160
4.275
4,310
4.186
4,221
4,336
4.247
LP
0
2.774
2,716
2.731
2.814
2.672
2,756
2.770
2.712
H8
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
LS
257
0
688
411
0
1,006
688
411
1.006
RD
0
0
0
350
0
360
0
350
350
HP/HS
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
HP/L8
0
24
114
24
24
114
114
24
114
LP/H8
0
0
0
18
0
18
0
18

LP/LS
0
16
74
16
16
74
74
16

NRD
32,840
0
0
7.777
0
7.777
0
7.777

Total
33.098
7.063
7.750
16.602
7,164
16,197
7,850
15.702

Candidate hazard levels examined ranged up to 3000 ppm for soil, 2000 ppm for dust, and 22 mg/cm' for paint.
Abatement Codes
HP = High Paint Abatement
LP = Low Paint Abatement
HS = High Soil Abatement
LS = Low Soil Abatement
RD = Recurrent Oust Abatement
                     HP/HS = High Paint, High Soil Abatements
                     HP/LS = High Paint, Low Soil Abatements
                     LP/HS = Low Paint. High Soil Abatements
                     LP/LS = Low Paint, Low Soil Abatements
                     NR D =  Nonrecurrent Dust Abatement
Voluntary Optimum:

Paint Condition Only:


Single Medium:


2-Media:


3-Media:
  Each home selects abatement (or no abatement) that has the highest net benefits

  Abatement Is recommended for homes with more than five square feet of lead-based paint in nonintact condition, regardless of XRF level or net
benefits. Homeowners choose the paint abatement method that generates the highest net benefits.

  Within the full range of individual soil, dust, and paint hazard levels that could be set as a threshold for action, with no constraints placed on the other
two madia, the levels specified in the table maximize net benefits.

  Within the full range of Individual soil, dust, and paint hazard level combinations that could be set as a threshold for action, with no restriction on the
other medium, the levels specified In the table maximize net benefits.

  Within the full range of Individual soil, dust, and paint hazard level comblnationa that could be set as a threshold for action, the levels specified In the
table maximizes net benefits.

-------
                                                                           Exhibit 7-3

                                              Beneflt-Coit Results for Five Alternative Decision Rube. Lew Cost Scenario

'•
2.
3.
4.
5.

Voluntary Optimum
Paint Condition Only
Condition
2-Madia Plus
Condition

3a.
3b.
3c.
4a.
4b.
4c.
3-Media Plus Condition
Soil
Ippml
-
•
1.600
-
-
1.500
1.500
-
1.500
Dust
Ippm)
-
-
•
1,200
-
1,200
•
1.200
1,200
Paint
Img/em*)
-
-
-
-
20
-
20
20
20
Nonbitact Paint
Abatement
Recommended
No
Yea
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Benefits
II million)
58,703
7.566
15,647
33.193
7.630
39,382
15.711
33,256
39,446
Abatement
Costa
(»mflUon|
13.950
18.972
24.778
21.836
19,235
26,824
25,041
22,099
27.087
Nat Benefits
(Exclusive of
Testing Costs)
ItmlOionl
44.753
(11.405)
(9.130)
11.357
(11.605)
12,558
(9.330)
11.167
12.368
Total Number
of Abatements
77,738

10,649
15.602
7.164
18.776
10.750
15.702
18.877
Number of
Negative M*t
0

6.394
6.463
6.429
6.529
6,494
6.664

Candidate hazard levels examined ranged up to 3000 ppm for soil, 2000 ppm for dust, and 22 mg/cm' for paint.

Voluntary Optimum:             Each home selects abatement (or no abatement) that has the highest net benefits
Paint Condition Only:
Single Medium:
2-Medla:
3-Media:
  Abatement is recommended for homes with more than five square feet of lead-based paint In nonlntact condition, regardless of XRF level or net
benefits.  Homeowners choose the paint abatement method that generates the highest net benefits.

  Within the full range of individual soil, dust, and paint hazard levels that could be set as a threshold for action, with no constraints placed on the other
two media, the levels specified In the table maximize net benefits.

  Within the full range of individual soil, dust, and paint hazard level combinations that could be set as a threshold for action, with no restriction on the
other medium, the levels specified In the table maximize net benefits.

  Within the full range of individual soil, dust, and paint hazard level combinations that could be set as a threshold for action, the levels specified In the
table maximizes net benefits.

-------
                                                                                       Exhibit 7-4

                                                    Distribution of Abatement Choices lor Five Alternative Decision Rules. Low Cost Scenario

1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
Decision Rules
Voluntary Optimum
Paint Condition Only
Single Medium Plus
Condition
2-Media Rus
Condition

3a.
3b.
3c.
4a.
4b.
4c.
3-Media Plus Condition
Sod
(ppml

-
1,500
-
-
1,500
1,500
-
1,500
Dust
(ppml

-
-
1,200
-
1,200
-
1,200
1,200
Paint
(mg/em'l

-
-
-
20
-
20
20
20
Nonlntact Paint
Abatement
Recommended
No
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yes
Yea
Number of Homes Abated by Abatement Type (1000s)
HP
0
4,120
4,120
4,146
4,181
4,146
4,181
4,207
4,207
LP
131
2,716
2,708
2,672
2,756
2,664
2,747
2,712
2,704
HS
163
0
163
74
0
237
163
74
237
LS
3.545
0
3,423
411
0
3,423
3,423
411
3.423
RD
0
0
0
276
0
276
0
276
276
HP/HS
0
27
27
27
27
27
27
27
27
HP/LS
0
126
126
126
126
126
126
126
126
LP/H8
0
0
0
18
0
18
0
18
18
LP/LS
0
74
82
74
74
82
82
74
82
NRD
73.899
0
0
7.777
0
7.777
0
7.777
7.777
Total
77.738
7,063
10,649
16.602
7.164
18.776
10.760
16.702
18.877
Candidate hazard levels examined ranged up to 3000 ppm for soil, 2000 ppm for dust, and 22 mg/cm* for paint.
Abatement Codes
HP = High Paint Abatement
LP = Low Paint Abatement
HS = High Soil Abatement
LS = Low Soil Abatement
RD = Recurrent Dust Abatement
                     HP/HS = High Paint, High Soil Abatements
                     HP/LS = High Paint, Low Soil Abatements
                     LP/HS = Low Paint, High Soil Abatements
                     LP/LS = Low Paint, Low Soil Abatements
                     NR D = Nonrecurrent Dust Abatement
Voluntary Optimum:

Paint Condition Only:


Single Medium:


2-Media:


3-Media:
  Each home selects abatement (or no ebatement) that has the highest net benefits

  Abatement la recommended for homes with more than five square feet of lead-baaed paint in nonlntact condition, regardless of XRF level or net
benefits. Homeowners choose the paint abatement method that generates the highest net benefits.

  Within the full range of Individual soil, duat, and paint hazard levels that could be set as a threshold for action, with no constraints placed on the other
two media, the levels specified in the table maximize net benefits.

  Within the full range of individual soil, dust, and paint hazard level combinations that could be set as a threshold for action, with no restriction on the
other medium, the levels specified in the table maximize net benefits.

  Within the full range of Individual soil, dust, and paint hazard level combinations that could be set as a threshold for action, the levels specified in the
table maximizes net benefits.

-------
 7.3   ALTERNATIVE DISCOUNTING PROCEDURE

       The selection of a discount rate is one of the most debated features  of benefit-cost
 analyses of environmental policies. Fait of the concern driving the debate stems from a common
 feature of environmental policy, which is that costs tend to be incurred  in the present or near-
 term while benefits accrue mostly in the future and sometimes in the distant future. Because of
 the exponential nature of discounting, an increase in the discount rate leads to a greater than
 proportional reduction in future benefits (and costs to the extent there are any) and therefore,
 so the debate goes, discounting biases benefit-cost analysis against environmental regulations.
 The debate also has a theoretical dimension to it. As Pearce et al. point out, there are two
 reasons for discounting, which do not necessarily lead to the same rate (Pearce et al., 1989).
 One reason is to reflect the social rate of time  preference.  The other reason is to  reflect the
 social opportunity cost of capital.  Either a choice must be made between using one or the other,
 or, some method of combining the two must be employed.

       In the main analysis, a single discount rate of 796 was applied to both benefits and costs,
 as specified in recent guidance from the Office of Management and Budget.  As an alternative,
 a two-stage discounting procedure is considered  in this sensitivity analysis. This procedure uses
 the approach of combining the time and capital elements to discounting cited above and was
 issued as supplemental  guidelines for regulatory impact analysis by EPA in 1989 (Scheraga,
 1989). The first step of the procedure calls for annualizing capitalize costs using the marginal
 rate of return on private investment and adding any  operation and maintenance costs to the
 annualized figures.  A rate of 7% and periods of 10, 20, 30, 40, and 50 years for amortizing
 (annualizing) the capital cost were used in this application.  The second step entails discounting
 both the  benefit and cost streams using the consumption rate of interest.  As recommended in
 the guidelines,  a  rate of 3% was used.  The two-stage procedure is appropriate under certain
 circumstances.  The costs of abatement  have to be passed on to  consumers, since displaced
 consumption is  the means for expressing the opportunity cost of the abatement. That is the case
 for owner-occupants undertaking lead abatement, since they are also the consumers in question,
 and is a strong  possibility for renters but is dependent on market conditions.

       Using the two-stage discounting procedure produces a substantial shift in the magnitude
 of the estimated benefits and costs of abatement, resulting in much larger net benefits.2  (See
 Appendix 7-A for abatement scenario unit costs using the two-stage discounting procedure.) The
 best single indicator of the greater net benefits is that many of the estimated optimal hazard
 levels for dust  and soil are much more  stringent than those estimated  in the main analysis.
 Exhibit 7-5 summarizes the range of optimal hazard levels estimated using different amortization
 periods in the two-stage procedure.
             This outcome derives in part from the performance of the two-step procedure when the benefit and
cost streams are very different over time (Scheraga, 1989) and from the fact that the benefits in any given year are
about four times larger when the damages stemming from IQ losses are discounted at 3% rather than 7%.

Abi Associates, Inc.                           7-10                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                        Exhibit 7-5

                                 Optimal Hazard Levels:
                      Results for Different Amortization Assumptions
Decision Rules
1.
2.
3.
Single Medium Plus
Condition
2-Media Plus
Condition
la.
Ib.
Ic.
2a.
2b.
2c.
3-Media Plus Condition
Soil
(ppm)
Min
300
-
-
1,000
700
-
1,000
Max
1000
-
-
2,200
1,000
-
2,200
Dust
(ppm)
Min
-
300
-
300
-
300
300
Max
-
400
-
400
-
400
400
Paint
(rag/cm2)
Min
-
-
4
-
4
20
20
Max
-
-
4
-
4
20
20
       The estimated optimal hazard level for dust experiences the clearest change from the main
 analysis.   The highest level under the two-stage procedure  is 400 ppm,  as opposed  to an
 optimum of 1,200 ppm in the main analysis.  The clear demarcation between the hazard  levels
 found using  the two-stage procedure and those found using the conventional 7% approach
 underscores how critical the decisions regarding the appropriate discount rate are. In this case,
 unlike in the  sensitivity analysis for costs, policy-relevant outcomes for dust  are significantly
 different between those of a model based upon one set of assumptions and those of a model
 based upon a  credible set of alternative assumptions.

       The estimated hazard  level  for  soil is  much more  dependent on the amortization
 assumptions made.3  At the  high end of the assumed range, meaning that costs are amortized
 over  fifty years, an optimal  hazard level  of 2,200 ppm for soil is estimated.  At the low end,
 where costs are amortized over ten years, an optimal hazard level of 300 ppm is estimated, at
 least  for a single medium decision rule for soil.   The range of values is narrower once the
 comparison is put on more equal footing.  When the comparison is restricted to the decision rule
 having the highest  net benefits under each amortization assumption, the optimal hazard  levels
 range from 1,000 ppm to 2,200 ppm.  Exhibits 7-6 to 7-15 provide the benefit-cost  results and
              The amortization period is the time period over which the initial capita] investment is recovered.
It matters so much because the two-stage procedure shares reflects the opportunity cost of capital that cannot be put
to other uses.  The longer the time period over which the capital is amortized, the longer the capital is displaced.
Five iterations of the two-stage discounting procedure were estimated, based on amortization periods of 10, 20,30,
40,  and SO years respectively.   The iteration based upon SO years results in the highest present value of the
aggregate abatement costs and the iteration based upon 10 years, the lowest. Consequently the 50-year version leads
to the least stringent hazard levels and the 10-year one to the most stringent levels.
Abt Associates, Inc.
7-11
Draft, January 10. 1994

-------
 abatement distributions for each of the five amortization analyses: 50,40, 30,20, and 10 years.
 These show that the turning point, from an optimal hazard level for soil of 2,200 ppm to one
 of 1,000 ppm occurs between the analysis based upon a thirty-year period and that based upon
 a twenty-year period.  This finding raises  the question of whether a choice between the higher
 and  lower hazard levels  can  be justified by  definitively establishing what the appropriate
 amortization period is.

        The appropriate amortization period depends on  what is assumed about the economic
 depreciation of the lead abatement.  Viewed as a form of home improvement, the lead
 abatement can add to the capital value of the home.  The capital value reflects the present
 discounted value of the stream of services that come from the lead abatement in the future.
 When those future services no longer have value, the capital  is fully depreciated.

        Determining when the lead abatement no longer  provides services of value is difficult.
 At one extreme, all valuable services disappear when the home, because it is to be replaced,
 is destroyed. The frequency of such an occurence can be estimated from the predicted
 disappearance rate for homes.  In this analysis, homes are assumed to have half-lives greater
 than the longest amortization period,  seeming to indicate that an amortization period of fifty
 years should be used.  Still, this example offers insufficient guidance since the value of
 having a lead-abated home could be zero even if the home is still standing.  For example, if
 lead-free homes are in much greater relative abundance  in the future, the added value of a
 lead-abated home should disappear.4

        As a result, even though it is reasonable to expect that lead-abated homes could
 command  higher prices in the near future, it is unknown when the housing market will no
 longer place an added value on a lead-abated home.  It does not appear possible to make a
 definitive choice between the more stringent optimal hazard levels based upon twenty or
 fewer years for amortization and the less stringent levels based upon thirty  or more years of
 amortization.3

       As for other rules which do not estimate optimal  hazard levels, the amortization
 assumptions vary in their significance. They are mostly irrelevant for the voluntary
 optimum.  The two-stage discounting procedure is significant only because  of the magnitude
 of the estimated net benefits and the numbers and types of abatements.  The net benefits
              Even today in urban housing markets where there are relatively few homes with lead contamination
the market value of a lead-abated activities would be small.

              As a last resort, it might appear that a case could be made that the relevant time period is no more
than twenty years based upon the length of payback periods of home improvement loans and of loans made to real
estate developers and landlords. Each of these have been asserted to be less than twenty years typically. However,
these norms are not directly linked to the value of the services from the home improvement, which can last longer
than the life of the loan. Even if in fifteen years the investment is fully recovered for the homeowner who initiated
the home improvement, and capital is no longer displaced, the subsequent owner may still pay a premium for the
home because of the improvement.  Once again, whether this is the case depends on the value that the housing
market places on lead-abated homes at that time.  Consequently, it does not seem that the choice between amortizing
over twenty years or thirty years can be settled by appealing to current loan practices.

Abt Associates, Inc.                            7-12                        Draft. January 10. 1994

-------
 range from $364 to $409 billion, or approximately eleven to twelve times larger. At these
 levels, it is not surprising that more expensive abatements that had not been chosen before
 are now chosen, at least to a small degree.  While more than 86% of the choices are still
 nonrecurrent dust abatements, all abatement alternatives are chosen under the 20-year, 30-
 year, and 40-year amortization analyses and all but one hi the other two analyses.  Finally, it
 should be noted that the two-staged procedure does not change the relative ranking of the
 voluntary optimum among all the decision rules considered. Furthermore, in absolute terms,
 the gap between the net benefits of the voluntary optimum and those of the other rules
 actually grows by a factor of three.

        For the paint condition rule, the amortization assumptions in the two-stage discounting
 procedure matter since they determine the difference between circumstances, where the net
 benefits are even more negative than under the main analysis (-$24 billion versus -$17
 billion), as is the case when amortization takes place over fifty years, and circumstances
 where the net benefits are positive for the first time ($0.6 billion), as is the case when an
 amortization of ten years is assumed.  These findings do not change the general conclusion
 from the main analysis that other decision rules have a far stronger economic justification
 than the paint condition rule does.

        In conclusion, the two-stage discounting procedure has the greatest implications for
 choosing hazard levels  under  Section 403 because it raises the possibility of a wider range of
 potentially optimal hazard levels for dust and soil. The gap for the dust hazard level ranges
 from 300 ppm to 1,200 ppm.6 For the soil hazard level, the gap ranges from 1,000 ppm to
 2,300 ppm.   The current analysis cannot categorically support the selection of one hazard
 level for dust and soil from each of these ranges.

        Several important things remain constant between the main analysis and this
 sensitivity analysis.  The voluntary optimum is far away the rule generating the highest net
 benefits and the paint condition rule typically the least (and virtually always negative). The
 types of decision rules that involve hazard levels for dust and soil and that have the highest
 net benefits are  generally the same under the two-stage procedure as they are in the main
 analysis.  They  are the  single-medium dust rule, the two-media rules  based upon soil and
 dust and upon dust and paint,  and the three-media rule.
              Although the amortization discussion focussed on its influence on the optimal soil hazard level,
it also matters to the question of which dust hazard level is optimal. A level of 400 ppm is optimal if amortization
periods of forty or fifty years are assumed, and 300 ppm otherwise.

Abt Associates, Inc.                           7-13                        Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                                                             Exhibit 7-6

                                        Benefit-Coot Results for Five Alternative Decision Rules. Two Stage Dboounting: 60 Years


2.
3.
4.
5.
Decision Rules
Voluntary Optimum
Paint Condition Only
Single Medium Plua
Condition
2-Media Plua
Condition

3a.
3b.
3e.
4a.
4b.
4c.
3-Madia Plua Condition
Soil
Ippml
-
-
1.000
-
-
2.200
1.000
-
2.200
Oust
(ppml
-
-
-
400
-
400
•
400
400
Paint
(mgfem'l
-
•
-
•
4
•
4
20
20
NonurtMrt Paint
AD 8V0IVI0 HI
nSOOIItlffWfMiB a
No
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Benefits
l» millionl
501.319
46.748
119.001
462.385
123.802
462.385
179.780
462.766
462.766
Abatement
Costa
It minion)
136.957
71.216
113.688
205.427
134.544
205.427
168.169
206.359
206.359
N01 BSftAffitV
(Eiohnlva of
Testing Costal
I* mBHonl
364.362
124.4671
5.313
256.959
(10.743)
256.959
11.611
256.408
256.408
Total Number
of Abatementa
. HOOOa)
79.268
7.063
11.586
43.883
12.262
43.883
15.869
43.983
43.983
Number of
Benaflta dOOOal
0
5.667
5.779
8.684
8.034
8.684
8.034
8.784
8.784
Candidate hazard levels examined ranged up to 3000 ppm lor aoil. 2000 ppm for duet, and 22 mg/om1 for paint.
Voluntary Optimum:

Paint Condition Only:


Single Medium:


2-Media:


3-Media:
  Each home selects abatement (or no abatement) that has the highest net benefits

  Abatement is recommended for homes with more then five square feet of lead-baaed paint in nonlntact condition, regardless of mg/cm' level or net
benefits. Homeowners choose the paint abatement method that generates the highest net benefits.

  Within the full range of individual aoil.  dust, and paint hazard levels that could be set as a threshold for action, with no constraints placed on the other
two media, the levels apecified in the table maximize net benefits.

  Within the full range of individual aoil.  dust, and paint hazard level combinations that could be sst as a threshold for action, with no restriction on the
other medium, the levels apaoifiad in the table maximize net benefits.

  Within the full range of individual aoil.  duat. end paint hazard level combinations that oould be eat aa a threshold for action, the levels specified hi the
table maximizes net benefits.

-------
                                                                                     Exhibit 7-7

                                           Distribution of Abatement Choices for Five Alternative Decision Rule*. Two Stage Discounting:  60 Yeare

1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
Deoteiofi Rules
Voluntary Optimum
Paint Condition Only
Single Medium Plus
Condition
2-Media Plus
Condition

3a.
3b.
3o.
4a.
4b.
4e.
3-Modia Plus Condition
SoH
Ippml

•
1.000
-
•
2.200
1.000
-
2.200
Dust
(ppm)

-
-
400
-
400
-
400
400
Paint
(mg/om'l

-
-
-
4
•
4
20
20
Nonifft AOI rBint
Abatement
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Number of Homes Abated by Abatement Type 11000s)
HP
367
4.137
4.137
4.463
7.049
4.463
7.049
4.524
4.524
LP
187
2.521
2.507
1.990
3.806
1.990
3.748
2.030
2.030
HS
1.808
0
921
1.584
0
1.584
780
1.584
1.584
IS
3.616
0
3.534
2.762
0
2.762
2.828
2.762
2.762
RD
2.744
0
0
5.681
0
5.681
0
5.681
5.681
HP/HS
21
161
228
375
512
375
512
375
375
HP/LS
0
126
126
803
486
803
486
803
803
IP/HS
8
36
36
27
92
27
92
27
27
IPOS
16
82
86
0
317
0
375
0
0
NRD
70.500
0
0
26.198
0
26.198
0
26.198
26.198
Total
78.268
7.063
11.586
43.883
12.262
43.883
15.869
43.983
43.983
Candidate hazard levels examined ranged up to 3000 ppm for soil. 2000 ppm for dust, and 22 mg/cm' for paint.
Abatement Codes
HP = High Paint Abatement
LP = Low Paint Abatement
HS = High Soil Abatement
LS " Low Soil Abatement
RD = Recurrent Dust Abatement
Voluntary Optimum:

Paint Condition Only.


Singla Medium:


2-Media:


3-Media:
                     HP/HS - High Paint. High Soil Abatements
                     HP/LS = High Paint. Low Soil Abatements
                     LP/HS o Low Paint. High Soil Abatements
                     LP/LS o Low Paint. Low Soil Abatements
                     NR D  " Nonrecurrent Duet Abatement

  Each home select* abatement (or no abatement) that has tha highest net benefits
 Abatement m recommended for homes with more than five square feet of lead-based paint in nonlntoot condition, regardless of mg/om' level or not
benefits. Homeowners choose the paint ebetement method that generates the highest net benefits.

 Within the full range of individual soil. dust, and paint hazard levels that could be set as a threshold for action, with no constraints placed on tha other
two media, the levels specified in the table maximize net benefits.

 Within the full range of individual eoil, dust, and paint hazard level combinations that could be set as a threshold for action, with no restriction on tha
other medium, the levels specified in the table maximize net benefits.

 Within the full range of individual eoil. dust, and paint hazard level combinations that could be set as a threshold for action, tha levels specified In the
table maximizes net benefits.

-------
                                                                             Exhibit 7-8

                                        Benefit-Co* Result! for Five AHernetive Decision Rule..  Two Stege Discounting: 40 Years

I-
2.
3.
4.
5.

Voluntary Optimum
Paint Condition Only
Single Medium Plus
Condition
2-Modia Plue
Condition

3b.
3c.
4e.
4b.
4o.
3-Media Plua Condition
(ppml
•
-
1.000
-
-
2.200
1.000
-
2.200
Ippml
•
-
-
400
-
400
-
400
400
Paint
(mg/om'l
•
•
-
•
4
-
4
20
20
Nofiintaot Paint
Abatement

No
Yee
Yea
Yes
Yes
Yee
Yes
Yes
Yes
Benefits
ItmOBon)
502.912
47.301
119.554
462.385
126.107
462.385
182.085
462.766
462.766
Abatement
Costs
It rnOHonl
132.648
66.892
108.363
196.613
127.849
196.613
160.678
197.480
197.480
Prai Benefite
(Exclusive of
Testing Costs)
l« mitten)
370.264
(19.5911
11.191
265.772
(1.742)
265.772
21.406
265.286
265.286
Total Number
of Abatements
(1000s)
79.307
7.063
11.586
43.883
12.262
43.883
16.869
43.983
43.983
Number off
UmmmtluM- ju^t
ntjgnive ram
0

5.740
8.628
7.929
8.628
7.929
8.728

Candidate hazard levels examined ranged up to 3000 ppm for soil. 2000 ppm for dust, and 22 mg/om> for paint.

                               Each home eelects  abatement (or no abatement) that has the highest net benefits
Voluntary Optimum:

Paint Condition Only:


Single Medium:


2-Media:


3-Media:
                               Abatement is recommended for homes with more than five square feet of lead-based paint in nonintaot condition, regardless of mg/cm1 level or net
                             benefits. Homeowners choose the paint abatement method that generates the highest net benefits.

                               Within the full range of individual soil. dust, and paint hazard levels that could be set as a threshold for action, with no constraints placed on the other
                             two medie. the levels specified in the table maximize net benefits.

                               Within the full range of individual soil. dust, and paint hazard level combinations that eould be eat as a threshold for action, with no restriction on the
                             other medium, the levels specified in the table maximize net benefits.

                               Within the full range of individual soil. dust, and paint hazard level combinations that could be eat as a threshold for action, the levels specified in the
                             table maximizes net benefits.

-------
                                                                                      Exhibit 7-9

                                            Distribution of Abatement Choices for Five Alternative Deoblon Rule..  Two Stage Discounting: 40 Year.


2.

4.




Condition
2-Media Plua
Condition

3a.
3b.
3o.
4a.
4b.
4c.
3-Medie Plua Condition
Ippml





2.200
1.000

2.200
Ippml


-

•
400
-
400
400
(mg/om'l


•
•
4
-
4
20
20
Nonintaot Psint
Abatement
RttOORini 8IM Ad


Yea

Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
. Number of Homee Abated by Abatement Type HOOOel
HP

4.188
4.188
4.463
7.258
4.463
7.2S8
4.524
4.524
LP
165
2.470
2.457
1.990
3.596
1.990
3.538
2.030
2.030
H8


921
1.584
0
1.584
780
1.584
1.584
18
3.557

3.534
2.762
0
2.762
2.828
2.762
2.762
RD


0
5.681
0
5.681
0
5.681
5.681
HP/MS


237
375
550
375
550
375

HP/IS

126
126
803
486
803
486
803

LP/H8
8
27

27
54
27
54
27

LP/LS

82
96
0
317
0
375
0

NRD
70.441

0
26.198
0
26.198
0
26.198

Total



43.883
12.262
43.883
16.869
43.983

Candidate hazard levels examined ranged up to 3000 ppm for eoil. 2000 ppm for duet, and 22 mg/cm' for paint.
Abatement Codes
HP - High Paint Abatement
LP - Low Paint Abatement
HS - High Soil Abatement
LS - Low Soil Abatement
RD " Recurrent Oust Abatement
Voluntary Optimum:

Point Condition Only:


Single Medium:


2-Media:


3-Media:
                     HP/HS - High Paint. High Soil Abatements
                     HP/LS  - High Paint. Low Soil Abatements
                     LP/HS  - Low Paint. High Soil Abatements
                     LP/LS = Low Paint. Low Soil Abatements
                     NR D = Nonrecurrent Duet Abatement

  Each home aelaeta abatement lor no abatement) that has the highest net benefit*
  Abatement is recommended for homes with more than five square feet of lead-baaed paint in nonfntaot condition, regardless of mg/cm« level or net
benefits. Homeowners choose the paint abatement method that generates the highest net benefits.

  Within the full renge of individual aoil. duat. and paint hazard levels that could be eat as a threshold for action, with no constraint, placed on the other
two media, the levels specified in the table maximize net benefite.

  Within the full range of individual aoil. dust, and paint hazard level combinations that could be eat aa a threahold for action, with no restriction on the
other medium, the levels specified in the table maximize net benefite.

  Within the full range of individual aoil. duat. and paint hazard level combinations that could be aet aa a threahold for action, the levels apecified in the
table maximizes net benefits.

-------
                                                                            Exhibit 7-10

                                        Benefit-Coat Result* for Five Alternative Decision Rule*. Two Stage Diaoounting: 30 Yeara

'•
2.
3.





Single Medium Plus
Condition
Condition

3b.
3e.
4b.
4c.

Ippml

•

-
•
2.200

•

Ippml

•
-
300
-

•
300

Img/om'l

-
-
•
4
•
4
20

NofiintBot Pfllnt
Abatement
Hfloo n i Hie no ttd
No
Yea
Yee
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yes
Yea
Benefite
I* milHonl
512.547
48.663
121.102
539.335
131.779
535.036
189.535
535.210
535.210
Abatement
Coeta
1* minion)
134.511
62.418
102.885
234.110
122.576
253.424
155.221
253.630
253.630
Net Benefite
lEiohnhra of
Tearing Coatal
(»miIBon)
378.036
113.755)
18.217
305.225

281.613
33.314
281.680
281.580
Total Number
of Abatementa
MOOOe)
78.406

11.686
51.978
12.282
51.978
16.869


Number of
Negative Net



9.052


7.684
9.944

Candidate hazard levels examined ranged up to 3000 ppm for aoil. 2000 ppm for duet, and 22 mo/cm* for paint.

                               Each home eelecte abatement (or no abatement) that haa the highest net benefits
Voluntary Optimum:

Paint Condition Only:


Single Medium:


2-Media:


3-Media:
                               Abatement ia recommended for homes with more than five square feet of lead-baaed paint in nonintaet condition, regardleaa of rng/em* lava) or net
                             benefits. Homeowners chooae the pnnt abatement method that ganeratea the Mghaat net benefits.

                               Within the full range of individual aoil. duat. and paint hazard lavela that could be eat aa a threshold for action, with no constraints placed on the other
                             two media, the levels specified in the teble maximize net benefits.

                               Within the full renge of individual aoil. duat. and paint hazard level combinationa that could be eat aa a threshold for action, with no restriction on the
                             other medium, the levels apacified in the teble maximize net benefita.

                               Within the full renge of individual aoil. duat. and paint hazard level combinationa that could be eet aa a threshold for action, the level* spsoified In the
                             table maximizes net benefits.

-------
                                                                                     Exhibit 7-11

                                           Distribution ol Abatement Choices for Five Alternative Decision Rules. Two Stage Discounting: 30 Veers

I-
2.
3.
4.
5.

Voluntary Optimum
Paint Condition Only
Single Medium Plue
Condition
2-Medie Plue
Condition

3a.
3b.
3c.
4a.
4b.
4c.
3-Media Plus Condition
Ippm)

•
1.000

•
2.200
700
-
2.200
(ppml

-
•
300
•
300
-
300
300
Img/om'l

-
•
•
4
-
4
20
20
Nonintaot Paint
Abatement

No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Ye*
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Number of Homes Abated by Abatement Type 11000s)
HP
1.532
4.290
4.290
8.082
7.684
5.647
7.684
5.748
5.748
LP
213
2.368
2.354
1.885
3.171
1.885
3.113
•1.88S
1.885
HS
2.319
0
921
5.827
0
5.548
780
5.548
6.548
LS
3.444
0
3.534
0
0
0
2.828
0
0
RD
1.684
0
0
4.154
0
5.046
0
4.945
4.945
HP/HS
112
170
251
1.952
550
1.775
608
1.775
1.775
HP/LS
172
185
185
0
730
0
730
0
0
LP/HS
8
27
27
27
54
27
54
27
27
IP/LS
18
24
24
0
74
0
74
0
0
NRD
69.907
0
0
32.050
0
32.050
0
32.050

Total
79.408
7.063
11.588
61.978
12.262
51.978
16.869
51.978

Candidate hazard levels examined ranged up to 3000 ppm for soil. 2000 ppm for dust, and 22 mg/cm» for paint.
Abatement Codes
HP - High Paint Abatement
LP •> Low Paint Abatement
HS m High Soil Abatement
LS ° Low Soil Abatement
RD = Recurrent Dust Abatement
Voluntary Optimum:

Paint Condition Only:


Single Medium:


2-Media:


3-Medie:
                     HP/HS = High Paint. High Soil Abatements
                     HP/LS = High Paint. Low Soil Abatements
                     LP/HS = Low Paint. High Soil Abatements
                     LP/LS = Low Paint. Low Soil Abatements
                     NR D  B Nonrecurrent Dust Abatement

  Each home seleete abatement lor no abatement) that has the highest net benefit*
  Abatement is recommended for homes with more than five square feet of lead-based paint in nonintaot condition, regardless of mg/em1 Isvel or not
benefits. Homeowners choose the paint abatement method that generates the higheat net benefit*.
  Within the full range of individual soil. dust, and paint hazard level* that could be set as a threshold lor action, with no cor
two medie. the levels specified in the table maximize net benefits.
nt* placed on the other
  Within the full range of individual eoH. dust, end paint hazard level combinations that could be eet as a threshold for action, with no restriction on the
other medium, the levels specified in the table meximize net benefita.

  Within the full range of individual soil. duct, and paint hazard level combination* that could be set a* a threshold for action, the levels specified in the
table maximizes nst benefite.

-------
                                                                            Exhibit 7-12

                                        Benefit-Co*! Result* for Five AHernetive Deohien Rule*. Two Stage Discounting: 20 Year*

1.
2.
3.
4.
5.

Voluntary Optimum
Paint Condition Only
Single Medium Hue
Condition
2-Media Plua
Condition

3a.
3b.
3c.
4a.
4b.
4o.
3-Madia Plua Condition
Soil
Ippml
-
-
300
-
-
1.000
700
-
1.000
Dual
Ippml
-
-
-
300
-
300
-
300
300
Paint
Img/om'l
-
-
-
-
4
•
4
20
20
NOfnfllBOt r Blflt
Abatement
Hftooin mono AQ
No
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Benefit*
1$ million)
533.242
49.546
260.929
539.335
135.152
540.104
236.203
639.335
540.104
Abatement
Coate
I* million)
142.387
56.524
228.815
234.110
112.951
234.617
183.622
234.110
234.617
N01 B0IWltta9
(Exotuslva of
Teetmg Coat*)
((rniUonl
390.854
16.978)
32.114
305.225
22.200
305.487
62.581
305.225
305.487
Total Number
of Abatement*
(lOOOal
79.689
7.063
18.777
51.978
12.262
52.045
18.171
51.978
52.045
Number of
Abatement* with
Negative Not
Benefita HOOOa)
0
5.150
9.684
9.052
7.274
9.052
8.790
9.052
9.052
Candidate hazard levels examined ranged up to 3000 ppm lor *oil. 2000 ppm for duat. and 22 mg/cm1 for point.
Voluntary Optimum:

Paint Condition Only:


Single Medium:


2-Media:


3-Media:
  Each home select* abatement lor no abatement) that has the highest net benefit*

  Abatement is recommended for homes with more than five square feet of lead-baaed paint in nonintect condition, regardlese of mg/om* level or net
benefit*. Homeowners ohooae the paint abatement method that generates the highest net benefits,

  Within the full renge of individual aoil.  duet, and paint hazard laveb that could be eat as a threshold for action, with no eonatralnta placed on the other
two madia, the level* apecified in the table maximize net benefits.

  Within the full renge of individual aoil.  duat. and paint hazard level combination* that could be eat e* a threshold for action, with no restriction on the
other medium, the level* epecified in the table maximize net benefit*.

  Within the full range of individual aoU.  duet, and paint hazard level combination* that could be set a* a threshold for action, the level* epeoified in the
table maximize* net benefit*.

-------
                                                                                    Exhibit  7-13

                                           Distribution ol Abatement Choices for Five Alternative DeoMon Rides. Two Stage Discounting: 20 Yeara

1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
Deobion Rule*
Voluntary Optimum
Paint Condition Only
Single Medium Plus
Condition
2-Medie Plus
Condition

3a.
3b.
3c.
4a.
4b.
4c.
3-Media Plue Condition
Soil
(ppml

•
300
-
-
1.000
700
•
1.000
Dint
Ippml

-
•
300
-
300
•
300
300
Paint
Imgfom')

•
-
-
4
-
4
20
20
Noniiitoot Pflint
Abatement

No
Yes
Yea
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

HP
2.198
4.317
3.612
6.082
7.795
6.082
7.649
6.082
6.082
Number of Homes Abated by Abatement Type (1000s)
LP
190
2.319
1.998
1.885
2.966
1.885
2.779
1.885
1.885
H8
4.670
0
9.198
5.827
0
5.895
5.433
6.827
5.895
L8
1.092
0
0
0
0
0
477
0
0
RD
1.387
0
0
4.154
0
4.154
0
4.154
4.154
HP/H8
169
205
3.745
1.952
656
1.952
894
1.952
1.952
HP/IB
188
188
0
0
783
0
783
0
0
IP/HS
8
27
223
27
54
27
150
27
27
LP/L8
0
8
0
0
8
0
8
0
0
NRD
69.786
0
0
32.050
0
32.050
0
32.060
32.060
Total
79.688
7.063
18.777
61.978
12.262
52.046
18.171
51.978
52.046
Candidate hazard levels examined ranged up to 3000 ppm tor aoil. 2000 ppm for dust, and 22 mg/cm' for paint.
Abatement Codes
HP - High Paint Abatement
LP = Low Point Abatement
HS - High Soil Abatement
LS <• Low Soil Abatement
RO - Recurrent Dust Abatement
Voluntary Optimum:

Paint Condition Only:


Single Medium:


2-Medie:


3-Media:
                     HP/HS i High Paint. High Soil Abatements
                     HP/LS - High Paint. Low Soil Abatements
                     LP/HS - Low Point. High Soil Abatements
                     LP/LS - Low Paint. Low Soil Abatements
                     NR D  - Nonrecurrent Dust Abatement

  Each home selects abatement (or no abatement) that has tha highest net benefite
  Abatement is recommended for homee with more than five equara feet of lead-based paint in nonintact condition, regardless of mg/cm' (oval or net
benefits. Homeowners choose the paint abatement method that generates the highest net benefite.

  Within the full range of individual soil. duet, and paint hazard levels that could be set as e threshold for action, with no constraints placed on tha other
two media, the levels specified in the table maximize net benefits.

  Within the full range of individual soil. dust, and paint hazard level combinations that could be sst ae a threshold for action, with no restriction on the
other medium, the levele specified in the table maximize net benefits.

  Within the full range of individual eoil. duet, and point hazard level combinations that could be set'as a threshold for action, tha levele specified in the
table maximizee net benefits.

-------
                                                                            Exhibit 7-14

                                        Benefit-Cost Result, for Five Alternative Decision Rules.  Two Stage Dboounting: 10 Year.


2.

4.
*•


Point Condition Only
Condition
2-Modia Plus
Condition

3b.
3c.
4a.
4b.


Ippml

-

-
-
1.000
700
-

Ippml

•

300
-
300
-


(mg/om'|

•

-
4
-
4


Abatement



Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yes
Yea
Yea

Benefit.
<» million!
t
558.772
52.477
263.342
543.290
140.161
544.058
238.581
543.290
544.058
Abatement
Coata
I* million)
150.119
51.843
200.086
210.539
103.225
210.978
162.501

210.978
N0i BWMfil8
(Exohisivo of
Testing Coatel
408.653

63.257
332.751
36.936
333.080
76.081


Total Number
Of AOBf 0in0fn9
(1000.1
80.842
7.063
18.777
51.978
12.262
52.046
18.171
51.978

Number of
Negative Nat
0

8.386
8.352
6.512
8.352



Candidate hazard level, examined ranged up to 3000 ppm for soil. 2000 ppm for dust, and 22 mg/cm' for paint.


                               Each home selects abatement (or no abatement) that hee the higheat net benefrte
Voluntary Optimum:

Point Condition Only:



Single Medium:



2-Madia:



3-Media:
                               Abatement is recommended for homes with more than five square feat of lead-based paint in nonintoot condition, regardless of mg/orn' lava) or net
                             benefit.. Homeowner, chooaa the point abatement method that generate, the highest net benefits.


                               Within the full range of individual soil. dust, and paint hazard levels that could be sot as a threshold for action, with no constraints placed on the other
                             two madia, the levela apecified in the teble maximize net benefit..


                               Within the fuH range of individual eoil. duet, and point hazard level combinations that could be set as a threshold for action, with no restriction on the
                             other medium, the levels specified in the table maximize net benefits.


                               Within ths full range of individual aoH. duet, and point hazard level combinatione that could be eet aa a threshold for action, the levels specified In the
                             table maxhnizee net benefits.

-------
                                                                                    Exhibit 7-16

                                           Distribution of Abatement Choice* lor Five Alternative Deonion Ride*.  Two Stege Discounting: 10 Years


2.
3.
4.
5.
Decision Rules
Voluntary Optimum
Paint Condition Only
Single Medium Plus
Condition
2-Media Plus
Condition

3a.
3b.
3c.
4a.
4b.
4c.
3-Media Plus Condition
Soil
Ippml

-
300
-
-
1.000
700
•
1.000
Dust
Ippml

•
-
300
-
300
•
300
300
Paint
(mg/om'l

•
-
•
4
-
4
20
20
NOIWItBOf rBint
Abatement
RaTMMinniAlwlarf

No
Yea
Yea
Yes
Yea
Yea
Yes
Yea
Yea
Number of Homes Abated by Abatement Type HOOOel
HP
2.735
4.227
3.682
6.645
7.665
6.645
7.629
6.645
6.645
IP
178
2.202
1.828
1.871
2.764
1.871
2.682
1.871
1.871
HS
6.038
0
8.012
5.827
0
5.885
5.488
6.827
5.895
L8
537
0
0
0
0
0
411
0
0
RD
952
0
0
3.264
0
3.264
0
3.264
3.264
HP/HS
652
388
3.958
2.279
876
2.279
1.011
2.279
2.279
HP/IS
657
188
0
0
783
0
783
0
0
LP/HS
8
48
186
41
76
41
158
41
41
IP/18
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
NRD
68.085
0
0
32.050
0
32.050
0
32.050
32.050
Total
80.842
7.063
18.777
61.978
12.262
52.046
18.171
61.978
52.045
Candidate hazard laveb examined ranged up to 3000 ppm lor soil. 2000 ppm lor dust, end 22 mg/om' lor paint.
Abatement Codes
HP - High Paint Abatement
LP - Low Paint Abatement
HS - High Soil Abatement
LS » Low Soil Abatement
RD = Recurrent Duet Abatement
Voluntary Optimum:

Paint Condition Only:


Single Medium:


2-Media:
                     HP/HS - High Paint. High Soil Abatements
                     HP/IS - High Paint. Low Soil Abatements
                     LP/HS - Low Paint. High Soil Abatements
                     LP/LS - Low Paint. Low Soil Abatements
                     NR D - Nonrecurrent Dust Abatement

 Each home selects abatement (or no abatement) that has the highest net benefits
 Abatement is recommended lor homes with more then live square leet ol lead-based paint in nonintaot condition, regardless ol mg/om* level or net
benefits. Homeowners choose the paint abatement method that generates the highest net benefits.

 Within the lull range ol individual aoil. dust, and paint hazard levels that could be eat aa a threshold lor action, with no constraints placed on the other
two media, the levels specified in the table maximize net benefite.

 Within the lull range ol individual soil. dust, end paint hazard level combinations that could be eet as a threshold lor action, with no restriction on the
other medium, the levels specified in the table maximize net benefite.
                              Within the lull range of individual aoil. dust, and paint hazard level combinationa that eould be eet as a threshold lor action, the levels specified in the
                             table maximizes net benefits.

-------
 7.4   SUPPLEMENTAL BENEFITS FOR ADULTS AND EXISTING CHILDREN

       The main analysis presented in this report was based upon a model developed to
 consider the benefits to children by reducing lead exposure from the time of birth until the
 age of seven years through the abatement of lead contamination. Not only was the risk
 assessment focused on this population alone but the behavioral assumptions regarding lead
 abatement were integrally linked to the impending births of children.  This model structure
 reflects the fact that this population has been considered a primary target for measures to
 prevent residential exposures to lead-contaminated paint, dust, and soil.  There are however
 other populations that may benefit from reducing lead exposures. '

       One population that has not been included in the main analysis consists of children
 under the age of seven who are already present in homes during the first seven years of the
 modeling time frame.  Because the model is currently structured to consider only lead
 abatements in anticipation of a new child being bom into  homes, these "existing" children do
 not serve as triggers for making an abatement decision nor are the benefits from any
 abatement calculated for them.  These children need special attention only in the first seven
 years of the fifty years of analysis since in subsequent years all children younger than seven
 years old were bom during the time period being modelled.

       Little is known about the size of the benefits to children who have been exposed to
 high lead levels during, for example,  the first three-and-half years of their lives but avoid
 these exposures  in the remaining three-and-half years during which IQ development, in
 particular, could have been inhibited.  For the purposes of this sensitivity analysis, the
 original assumption regarding the motivation for abatement - the upcoming birth of a child -
 was maintained but the benefits from abatement for the child about to be born were
 supplemented by an estimate of the benefits to the expected number of children under seven
 already in the household.  The benefits for these existing children were a prorated portion of
 the benefits expected for a newborn.  In the first year of the model, for example, the
 representative  existing child was assumed to be three-and-a-half years old and to gain one-
 half the benefit that a newborn would from abatement.

       Other populations  for whom potential benefits of lead abatements are not currently
 considered in the model are older children and adults.  Adverse health effects are associated
 with elevated blood lead levels in individuals over the age of seven, and  there is a
 considerable body of information on the dose-response relationships between blood lead
 levels in adults and blood pressure. There is, however, scant information on the
 relationships between lead levels in paint, soil and dust and blood lead levels for populations
 over the age of seven (the ffiUBK model  only considers children up to seven years of age).
 It is therefore difficult to quantify the  changes in blood lead levels and the coincident changes
 in health status of adults associated with residential lead abatements.  As a "placeholder" for
 estimating the potential impacts of lead abatements, a method has been developed that draws
 upon information provided in recent report by the Centers for Disease Control (CDC). The
 CDC cites findings of Bornschein that the blood lead levels of pregnant women in homes
 with and without lead-based paint differed by 2.13 pg/dL  (Centers for Disease Control,
 1991). (As noted in Chapter 3, this information was also used in the main analysis for the
 computation of the incidence of neonatal mortality.) In this analysis,  this difference is

Abt Associates, Inc.                          7-24                       Draft. January JO, 1994

-------
applied to the case of adults living in homes where lead-based paint is abated in connection
with an impending birth to calculate the reduced probabilities of hypertension-related effects.
Reduced hypertension-related mortality is valued using $2 million per statistical life saved.
Certain reduced morbidity effects (non-fatal stroke and coronary heart disease) are valued
using 32% of the value of a statistical life saved.  Avoided hypertension is valued using
estimates of medical costs avoided. In sum, the per-abatement adult benefit is estimated as
$5,814.  More in-depth details can be found in (Abt Associates, Inc., 1993).

       The overall estimates that derive from supplementing the newborn child benefits in
the main analysis with benefits to existing children and adults should be viewed as illustrative
only, in light of the unrefined and somewhat arbitrary assumptions needed to generate the
supplemental benefit estimates.  The benefit-cost results are presented in Exhibit 7-16 and the
distribution of abatements selected in Exhibit 7-17.

       For all decision rules, the net benefits are higher in this sensitivity analysis than they
were under the main analysis of this report (Exhibits 6-18 and 6-19).  This is mostly
attributable to the inclusion of the adult benefits rather than the inclusion of the benefits to
existing children. Furthermore, the net benefits are positive for all decision rules, a rare
finding seen in only other version of the analysis (the two-stage discounting example based
on an amortization period of 10 years).  This outcome underscores how radical a departure
the addition of adult benefits is from the main analysis.  In the case of the voluntary
optimum, the net benefits are $7 billion higher.  For the remaining decision rules,  the
changes are even more dramatic.  The net benefits are $20 to $27 billion higher than they
were for these rules in the main analysis.

       In two cases (the paint condition only rule and the single-medium rule based upon soil
plus non-intact paint abatement), the number of abatements induced did not change. The net
benefits of these abatements changed dramatically though because of the supplemental adult
benefits associated with paint abatement.  The number of abatements under the voluntary
optimum increased by 9 million homes.  In the remainder of the cases the numbers of
abatements rose by 5 to 28 million homes.

       Although the change in benefits from the main analysis was only directly associated
with paint abatement, increases in the number of abatements were not restricted to paint
abatement. As shown in Exhibit 7-17,  nonrecurrent dust abatement, abatements that included
high-end paint abatement, and low-end  soil abatement showed the largest increases from the
results of the main analysis. Other forms of abatement in addition to paint abatement
increased in the optimum because formerly the houses needing paint abatement served as a
"roadblock" to going to lower soil or dust hazard levels in the optimum.  These houses had
negative net benefits from abatement and lowered the aggregate net benefits  in the  main
analysis even though other houses, with the same soil and/or dust levels, had positive net
benefits from soil or dust abatement. In the aggregate, the latter were not large enough to
outweigh the negative net benefits of the former. Consequently, in the main analysis, higher
hazard levels had higher aggregate net benefits.  Only once the benefits of paint abatement
were supplemented by the adult benefits was it possible for the aggregate net benefits of
more stringent soil and dust hazard levels to be the highest.
Abt Associates. Inc.                           7-25                       Draft. January 10. 1994

-------
       This phenomenon helps to explain why the hazard levels for soil and dust could
 decline when only the benefits for paint abatement were increased in this sensitivity analysis.
 The dust hazard level exhibited the most consistent decline, from 1,200 ppm in the main
 analysis to 400 ppm in all cases in this sensitivity analysis. This  reduction in the optimal
 dust level may have also been assisted by the possibility that lower dust levels can  be
 achieved through paint abatement.  The fact that the optimal three-media decision rule
 (1,400/400/20) and the optimal two-media decision rule involving dust and paint (--/400/20)
 both induce large numbers of paint abatements while the paint hazard level remains high
 seems to be consistent with this conclusion.  These two decision rules and the other two that
 involve a dust hazard level (the single-medium rule (-/400/~) and the two-media rule for
 soil and dust (1,400/4007-)) have net benefits of approximately $29.5 billion, the highest
 among the rules defining hazard levels.

       In view of the uncertainties associated with the benefits for adults and existing
 children in this particular sensitivity analysis, it is important to weigh its implications for
 policymaking very carefully. Of the three sensitivity analyses presented in this chapter,  this
 one may rest on the weakest analytical footing. However, since the optimal hazard levels
 identified in this analysis are consistent with the lower bounds of the optimal hazard levels
 identified in the previous two sensitivity analyses, the burden  of proof for the findings of this
 particular sensitivity analysis is not high.

       This analysis found an optimal hazard level for soil of 1,400 ppm.  A level  of 1,500
 ppm was optimal in the low cost scenario while a level of 1,000 ppm was the lowest optimal
 hazard level under the two-stage discounting procedure. The  optimal hazard level for dust in
 this sensitivity analysis  was 400 ppm.  The optimal level was  higher in the high and low cost
 scenarios (1,200 ppm) but the lower bound of the optimal hazard levels under the various
 two-stage discounting scenarios was  comparable (300 ppm). The  experience with paint
 hazard levels under this sensitivity analysis reproduced that of the two-stage procedure,
 where the optimal hazard level was variously 4 or 20 mg/cm2, depending upon the  decision
 rule, but the highest net benefits were based upon 20 mg/cm2.

       Taken  together,  the three sensitivity analyses presented in this chapter raise  the
 possibility of a wider range of potentially optimal hazard levels than the findings in the main
 analysis imply.  The optimal dust hazard level may be as low as 300 ppm or as high as
 1,200 ppm. The main analysis found a dust hazard level of 1,200 ppm. The optimal soil
 hazard level may be as  low as 1,000 ppm or as high  as 2,300 ppm.  The main analysis found
 a soil hazard level of 2,300 ppm. In the main analysis,  and in these sensitivity analyses, the
 highest net benefits for paint were associated  with a hazard level of mg/cm2. Finally, a
 qualitative hazard level  based upon paint condition typically entails negative net benefits with
 the exception of two cases:  this particular sensitivity analysis which linked supplemental
 benefits to paint abatement specifically and, the shortest-term amortization case (10 years)
 under the two-stage discounting procedure. These two cases still seem rare enough to raise
 doubts about the desirability of a paint condition criterion given the paint abatement options
 constructed for this analysis.
Abt Associates. Inc.                           7-26                       Draft, January 10. 1994

-------
                                                                          Exhibit 7-16

                                          Beneflt-Coet Results for Flwa Alternative Decision Ride*. Adults and Existing Children
Decision Rule*
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
Voluntary Optimum
Paint Condition Only
Singh Medium Phia
Condition
2-Modla Phit
Condition
3a.
3b.
3c.
4a.
4b.
4e.
3-Madia Phil Condition
Soil
(ppm)
-
-
2.300
.
.
1.400
2.300
.
1.400
Dual
(ppm)
-
-
-
400
.
400
.
400
400
Paint
mg/cm'
-
-
-
.
4
-
4
20
20
Nonintact Paint
AbfltBnwnt
noco rnrnonctod
No
Yaa
Yoa
YM
Yaa
Yaa
Yaa
Yaa
Yaa
Banafiti
(1 million)
100.116
37.015
44.081
123.754
70.910
123.754
72.853
1 24.247
124.247
Abatement
Costs
(I million)
58.720
34.838
41.192
94.262
62.053
94.262
63.473
94.749
94.749
Net Benaflta
(Exehialve of
Teatlng Coata)
It million)
41.396
2.177
2.890
29.492
8.858
29.492
9.380
29.498
29,498
Total Number
of AeMtwnonte
HOOOa)
54.558
7.063
8.069
43.883
12.262
43.883
1 2.673
43.983
43.983
Number of
AbfltwTMntc with
Negative Net
Benefit* (1000*1
0
4.241
4.710
11.168
6.733
11.168
5.733
11.168
11.168
Candidate hazard level* examined ranged up to 3000 ppm for *oil. 2000 ppm for du*t. and 22 mg/cm' for paint.
Voluntary Optimum:

Paint Condition Only:


Single Medium:


2-Madla:


3-Media:
 Each home aalecta abatement (or no abatement) that ha* the highest net benefite

 Abatement la recommended for home* with more then five equate feet of load-based paint in nonhrtaet condition, regardlm* of XRF level or net
benefit*. Homeowner* choose the paint abatement method that generate* the highest net benefit*.
 Within the full range of individual toil. dust, and paint hazard level* that could be let a* • threshold for action, with no <
two media, the level* specified in the table maximize net benefit*.
•tralnt* placed on the ether
 Within the full range of individual aoil. dint, and paint hazard level combination* that could be **t a* a threshold for action, with no restriction on the
other medium, the level* ipecified in the table maximize net benefit*.

 Within the full range of Individual aoll. dint, and paint hazard level combinetione that could be eet a* a threshold for action, the level* specified In the
table maximizes net benefit*.

-------
                                                                                                      Exhibit  7-17

                                                                 Distribution of Abat«m«nt Cholera for Flw. Alternative Decision Riaee. Adults and Existing Children

1.
2.
3.
4.
b.
Decision Rulea
Voluntary Optimum
Paint Condition Only
Single Medium Plus
Condition
2-Media Plus
Condition

3a.
3b.
3c.
4e.
4b.
4e.
3-Media Plus Condition
Soil
Ippml

•
2.300
-
-
1.400
2.300
•
1.400
Duet
(ppm)

•
•
400
•
400
•
400
400
Paint
mg/cm'

•
•
•
4
-
4
20
20
Nonintact Paint
Abatement
R0CO IIIIIMIIUBU
No
Yes
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea
Yea

HP
8.928
6.876
6.876
1 2.439
1 1 .479
1 2.439
1 1 .479
1 2.S40
1 2.540
Number of Homes Abated by Abatement Type (1000s)
LP
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
HS
0
0
0
967
0
967
0
967
967
LS
411
0
411
3.379
0
3.379
411
3.379
3.379
RD
0
0
0
879
0
879
0
879
879
HP/HS
0
0
0
233
0
233
0
233
233
HP/LS
314
188
783
1.269
783
1.269
783
1.289
1.269
LP/HS
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
LP/LS
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
NRD
44.906
0
0
24.716
0
24.716
0
24.716
24.716
Total
64.668
7.063
8.069
43.883
1 2.262
43.883
1 2.673
43.983
43.983
Candidate hazard levels examined ranged up to 3000 ppm for soil.  2000 ppm for dual, and 22 mg/cm' for paint.
Abatement Codee
HP - High Paint Abatement
LP - Low Paint Abatement
HS = High Soil Abatement
LS » Low Soli Abatement
RD = Recurrent Dual Abatement

Voluntary Optimum:

Paint Condition Only:
                     HP/HS - High Paint. High Soil Abatements
                     HP/LS -  High Paint. Low Soil Abatements
                     LP/HS =  Low Paint'. High Soil Abatements
                     LP/LS - Lew Paint. Low Soil Abatements
                     NR D • Nonrecurrent Dual Abatement
 Each home selects abate
                          nt (or no abatement) that has the highest net benefits
 Abatement is r<
                      mded for homes with more than five square feat of lead-baaed paint In nonlntaot condition, regardleaa of XRF (aval or net
                             benefits. Homeowners choose the paint abatement method that generates the highest net benefits.
2-Media:
3-Media:
       i the full range of Individual soil. dust, and paint hazard levels that could be set as a threshold for action, with no constraints placed on the other
two madia, the levels specified In the table maximize net benefits.

 Within the full range of individual aoil. dual, and paint hazard level combinations that could be set as a threshold for action, with no restriction on the
other medium, the levels specified in the table maximize net benefits.

 Within the full range of individual aoil. duet, and paint hazard level combinations that could be set es a threshold for action, the levels specified In the
table maximizes net benefits.

-------
7.5

Abt Associates, Inc.  1993.  Tide IV, Sections 402 and 404: Regulatory Impact Analysis.
       Draft final report prepared for Nicolaas Bouwes, Regulatory Impacts Branch,
       Economics, Exposure and Technology Division, Office of Pollution Prevention and
       Toxics, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Washington, DC,  October.

Centers for Disease Control, U.S. Department of Health and Human Services.  1991.
       Strategic Plan for the Elimination of Childhood Lead Poisoning, February.

Pearce, D., A. Markandya, and E. B. Barbier.  1989. Blueprint for a Green Economy.
       Earthscan Publications Ltd., London, p.  134.

Scheraga, J. 1989. Supplemental Guidelines on Discounting in the Preparation of
       Regulatory Impact Analyses.  Economic Studies Branch, Office of  Policy,
       Planning and Evaluation, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Washington,
       DC, March.
Abt Associates, Inc.                         7-29                      Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 7.A    APPENDIX

 As discussed in Section 7.1, a two-stage discounting procedure was used as an alternative to
 the straight seven percent discounting presented in Chapters 4-6.  Exhibit 7.A-1 shows the
 unit costs calculated for each of the ten abatement scenarios using amortization of twenty and
 thirty years. Because the reflect the social costs of displacing capital, these unit costs are
 higher than those calculated using a seven percent discount rate as shown in Exhibits 4-5 and
 4-6.
Abt Associates. Inc.                           7-30                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                                             Exhibit 7.A-1




                                  Summary of Abatement Strategy Unit Costs Using Two Stage Discounting
Abatement Scenario

High-end Paint Abatement


Low-end Paint Abatement


Non-Recurrent Dust


Recurrent Dust






Estimate Level

High
Medium
Low
High
Medium
Low
High
Medium
Low
Unit Cost by Amortization Period
10 Year
$15,485
$12,752
$10,020
$4,554
$3,340
$2,125
$1,457
$911
$364
20 Year
$17,905
$14,745
$11,585
$5,266
$3,862
$2,457
$1,685
$1,053
$421
30 Year
$20,139
$16,585
$13,031
$5,923
$4,344
$2,764
$1,895
$1,185
$474
40 Year
$22,106
$18,205
$14,304
$6,502
$4,768
$3,034
$2,081
$1,300
$520
50 Year
$23,771
$19,576
$15,381
$6,991
$5,127
$3,263
$2,237
$1,398
$559
Ten Year Monthly Total Coat P^timafo
High High $25,708
High Low $15,065
Low High $22,606
Low Low $11,964
Medium High $24,159
Medium Low $13,515
Abt Associates, Inc.
7-31
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                                              Exhibit 7.A-1




                                  Summary of Abatement Strategy Unit Costs Using Two Stage Discounting
Abatement Scenario
High-end Soil Abatement
Low-end Soil Abatement
Estimate Level
High cost
> 2000 ppm and exterior paint
£2000 ppm and exterior paint
>2000 ppm and no exterior paint
£2000 ppm and no exterior paint
Medium cost
> 2000 ppm and exterior paint
£2000 ppm and exterior paint
> 2000 ppm and no exterior paint
£2000 ppm and no exterior paint
Low cost
> 2000 ppm and exterior paint
£2000 ppm and exterior paint
>2000 ppm and no exterior paint
£2000 ppm and no exterior paint
Unit Cost by Amortization Period
High cost
$39,897
$24,715
$27,752
$12,570
Medium cost
$26,005
$15,786
$19,933
$9,714
Low cost
$15,757
$10,501
$12,114
$6,857
Hieh cost
$46,132
$28,578
$32,089
$14,535
Medium cost
$30,069
$18,253
$23,048
$11,232
Low cost
$18,220
$12,142
$14,007
$7,929
High cost
$51,888
$32,143
$36,092
$16,348
Medium cost
$33,821
$20,531
$25,923
$12,633
Low cost
$20,493
$13,657
$15,754
$8,918
Hithcost
$56,956
$35,283
$39,618
$17,945
Medium cost
$37,125
$22,536
$28.455
$13,867
Low cost
$22,495
$14,991
$17,293
$9,789
High cost
$61,245
$37,940
$42,601
$19,296
Medium cost
$39,920
$24,233
$30,598
$14,911
Low cost
$24,188
$16,119
$18,595
$10,526
High -$19, 178
Medium -$13, 3 10
Low - $7,442
Abt Associates, Inc.
7-32
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                                             Exhibit 7.A-1




                                  Summary of Abatement Strategy Unit Costs Using Two Stage Discounting
Abatement Scenario
High-end Paint and High-end Soil
High-end Paint and Low-end Soil
Estimate Level
High cost
>2000 ppm and exterior paint
£2000 ppm and exterior paint
> 2000 ppm and no exterior paint
£ 2000 ppm and no exterior paint
Medium cost
> 2000 ppm and exterior paint
£2000 ppm and exterior paint
> 2000 ppm and no exterior paint
£2000 ppm and no exterior paint
Low cost
> 2000 ppm and exterior paint
£2000 ppm and exterior paint
>2000 ppm and no exterior paint
£2000 ppm and no exterior paint
High
Medium
Low
Unit Cost by Amortization Period
Hieh cost
$55,382
$40,200
$43,237
$28,055
Medium cost
$38,757
$28,538
$32,685
$22,466
Low cost
$25,777
$20,521
$22,134
$16,877
$34,662
$26,062
$17,462
Hieh cost
$64,037
$46,483
$49,994
$32,440
Medium cost
$44,814
$32,998
$37,793
$25,977
Low cost
$29,806
$23,728
$25,593
$19,515
$37,083
$28,055
$19,027
High cost
$72,027
$52,282
$56,231
$36,487
Medium cost
$50,406
$37,116
$42,508
$29,218
Low cost
$33,524
$26,688
$28,785
$21,949
$39,317
$29,895
$20,473
Hieh cost
$79,062
$57,389
$61,724
$40,051
Medium cost
$55,330
$40,741
$46,660
$32,072
Low cost
$36,799
$29,295
$31,597
$24,093
$41,284
$31,515
$21,746
Hieh cost
$85,016
$61,711
$66,372
$43,067
Medium cost
$59,496
$43,809
$50,174
$34,487
Low cost
$39.569
$31,500
$33,967
$25,907
$42,949
$32,886
$22.823
Abt Associates, Inc.
7-33
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                                             Exhibit 7.A-1




                                  Summary of Abatement Strategy Unit Costs Using Two Stage Discounting
Abatement Scenario
Low-end Paint and High-end Soil
Low-end Paint and Low-end Soil
Estimate Level

High cost
>2000 ppm and exterior paint
£2000 ppm and exterior paint
> 2000 ppm and no exterior paint
2 2000 ppm and no exterior paint
Medium cost
> 2000 ppm and exterior paint
£2000 ppm and exterior paint
> 2000 ppm and no exterior paint
22000 ppm and no exterior paint
Low cost
> 2000 ppm and exterior paint
22000 ppm and exterior paint
>2000 ppm and no exterior paint
22000 ppm and no exterior paint
High
Medium
Low
Unit Cost by Amortization Period
High cost
$44,451
$29,269
$32,306
$17,124
Medium cost
$29,345
$19,126
$23,273
$13,054
Low cost
$17,882
$12,626
$14,239
$8,982
$23,732
$16,650
$9,567
Hidi cost
$51,398
$33,844
$37,355
$19,801
Medium cost
$33,931
$22,115
$26,910
$15,094
Low cost
$20,678
$14,600
$16,465
$10,387
$24,444
$17,172
$9,900
Hiiui cost
$57,810
$38,066
$42,015
$22,271
Medium cost
$38,165
$24,875
$30,267
$16,977
Low cost
$23,257
$16,421
$18,518
$11,682
$25,101
$17,654
$10,206
High cost
$63.458
$41,785
$46,120
$24.446
Medium cost
$41,893
$27.304
$33.223
$18.635
Low cost
$25,529
$18.025
$20,327
$12,823
$25,680
$18,078
$10,476
Hieh cost
$68,236
$44,931
$45,592
$26,287
Medium cost
$45.047
$29.360
$35,725
$20,038
Low cost
$27,451
$19.382
$21,858
$13,789
$26,169
$18,437
$10.705
Abt Associates, Inc.
7-34
Draft. January 10, 1994

-------
                       8. IMPACTS OF THE PROPOSED RULE
 8.1   REGULATORY FLEXIBILITY ANALYSIS

 8.1.1 Reason and Legal Basis for Agency Action

       The Agency is identifying lead-based paint hazards, lead-contaminated soil and lead
 contaminated dust under the Housing and Community Development Act which was enacted by
 Congress on October 28, 1992 and contains 16 separate Titles. Title X of the Act is named the
 Residential Lead-Based Paint Hazard Reduction Act of 1992 and is composed of five subtitles.
 One of these, Subtitle B, amends the Toxic Substances Control Act (TSCA) by adding Title IV-
 Lead Exposure Reduction.  TSCA Title IV includes twelve sections, from §401 through §412.
 Section 403, the subject of this analysis, reads as follows:

       Sec. 403. Identification of Dangerous Levels of Lead
       "Within 18 months after the enactment of this title, the Administrator  shall
       promulgate regulations which shall  identify, for purposes of this title and the
       Residential Lead-Based  Paint Hazard Reduction Act of 1992, lead-based paint
       hazards, lead-contaminated dust, and lead-contaminated soil."
       Section 403 by itself requires only the identification of lead hazard levels and does not
 require any specific action to abate residences whose contamination is above these levels.  Thus
 a formal regulatory flexibility analysis will not be done.  Instead, this section will identify small
 entities likely to be induced to abatement  activity by  the Agency's actions and discuss the
 availability of data to quantify the effects.  The approach taken is in keeping with the Regulatory
 Flexibility Act charter which suggests:

       "as a  principle of regulatory  issuance that  agencies  shall endeavor,
       consistent with the objectives of the rule and of applicable statutes, to fit
       regulatory  and informational requirements  to the scale of businesses,
       organizations and governmental jurisdictions subject to regulation.  To
       achieve this principle, agencies are required to solicit and consider flexible
       regulatory proposals and to explain the rationale for their actions to assure
       that such proposals are given serious consideration."

 The hazard levels the Agency sets will generate activity in two ways.  First, voluntary abatement
 is a likely response to the introduction of EPA these levels. This may impose a disproportionate
 burden on lower income homeowners and renters and  is addressed  by comparing income to
 abatement costs for individual homeowners as shown in Section 8.5.  Second, the levels set in
 Section 403 are used throughout Title X as the basis for determining appropriate responses to
 the existence of lead-based hazards.  The small business and government entities likely to be
 affected by various provisions of Title X are discussed below.
Abt Associates, Inc.                            8-1                        Draft. January 10, 1994

-------
 8.1.2  Definition of Small Entity and Affected Populations

        The first step in the analysis is to define small entity and the affected populations in a
 quantitative manner in order to determine the number affected. The definition should encompass
 small firms, small non-profit organizations and small governments.  The Section 403 regulation
 pertains to home-owners and landlords; in these cases, the typical definition of small business
 based on  the  number of  employees is  not relevant.   However, the "EPA Guidelines for
 Implementing the Regulatory Flexibility  Act" allows a re-definition of small entity  to suit the
 regulatory circumstances if the Office of Advocacy of the Small Business Administration is
 consulted and  public comment on the proposed alternative definitions is obtained.  For this
 regulation we suggest the typical housing industry definition of a small landlord, one who owns
 less than four units, as the appropriate  small business definition.  Definitions based  on the
 number of units are preferable to those based on revenue or number of employees because of
 the variability  of the latter two per housing unit. Small not-for-profit organizations could be
 defined in the same manner as the small business.   For small government jurisdictions,  the
 standard definition of a population less than 50,000 would apply.

       Exhibit 8-1 summarizes the discussion in Chapter 1  of the Housing and Community
 Development Act sections  where the levels set  in Section 403 are used.  The final column
 identifies the types of entities that may be affected. The sections of Title X that are most likely
 to disproportionately burden small entities are Sections 1012 and 1018.  The former requires
 reduction of hazards in rehabilitation projects receiving less than $25,000 per unit in Federal
 funds and abatement of hazards in those rehabilitation projects receiving more than $25,000 in
 Federal funds  per unit.  These additional hazard reduction actions could prove a financial
 burden. Section 1018 requires notification to the buyer of any property with a known lead-based
 paint hazard and gives the buyer the right to perform an inspection before being obligated to a
 contract for sale or lease. Small entities,  housing owners, might be disproportionately affected
 by  a decrease in market value of a home  if lead is found.
Abt Associates, Inc.                            8-2                        Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                                                                   EXHIBIT 8-1

                         Relationship of Identification of Lead Hazard Levels under § 403 with Other Provisions of the Lead-Based Paint Hazard Reduction Act
    Section
                             Affected Housing Stock or Entity
                                                                     Relationship
                                     Small Entities Affected by (403
                                     Hazard Levels
    81011 (a)
 Affordable non-public housing that ii not federally owned or assisted
 housing
                                                                                                 |403 Identification used to establish
                                                                                                 eligibility for receiving HUD grants for
                                                                                                 interim controls or abatement of lead-
                                                                                                 based paint hazards.
                                     No direct effects.  Indirect effect is a
                                     benefit for both large and small
                                     landlords.
    §1012
 Various housing receiving assistance under the Cranston-Gonzalez
 National Affordable Housing Act
                                                                                                 I) |403 Identification used to require
                                                                                                 reduction of hazards in course of
                                                                                                 rehabilitation projects receiving less than
                                                                                                 125,000 per unit in federal funds, and
                                                                                                 abatement of hazards in rehabilitation
                                                                                                 projects receiving more than $25,000 per
                                                                                                 unit.
                                                                                                 2) (403 Identification used to establish
                                                                                                 eligibility for receiving federal funds for
                                                                                                 interim controls or abatement of lead-
                                                                                                 baaed paint hazards.
                                                                                                 3) (403 Identification used to establish
                                                                                                 eligibility for including inspection and
                                                                                                 abatement costs in determining maximum
                                                                                                 monthly rents in federally assisted rental
                                                                                                 property.
                                     Could add lead reduction or abatement
                                     costs on top of rehabilitation coils.  The
                                     $25,000 ceiling is low enough that both
                                     small and large landlords will be
                                     affected.  This might be a greater
                                     financial  burden to small landlords.
   (1013
Federally owned housing being sold
                                                                                                 1) Housing built prior to 1960:
                                                                                                 Inspection and REQUIRED abatement of
                                                                                                 lead-based paint hazard (as identified by
                                                                                                 (403).
                                                                                                 2) Housing built between i960 and 1978:
                                                                                                 Inspection and written notification to
                                                                                                 buyer of all lead-based paint hazards (as
                                                                                                 identified by (403)
                                                                                                              Federally owned housing primarily from
                                                                                                              the Resolution Trust Corporation or
                                                                                                              Veteran's Administration or Housing
                                                                                                              and Urban Development.  Federal
                                                                                                              government is a large entity.
   (1014
Low-income housing units under jurisdiction of Cranston-Gonzalez
National Affordable Housing Act.
                                                                                                 (403 Identification used to estimate
                                                                                                 number of housing units in a jurisdiction
                                                                                                 occupied by low-income families that
                                                                                                 have a lead-based paint hazard.
                                                                                                 Information shall be used in preparing a
                                                                                                 housing strategy .
                                     Information dissemination only. No
                                     significant direct or indirect effect on
                                     small entities.
   (1015
Private housing.
                                                                                                 (403 Identification used by Inter-Agency
                                                                                                 Task Force to recommend programs and
                                                                                                 procedures for financing inspections and
                                                                                                 abatements.
                                                                                                              No direct effect on small entities.
                                                                                                              Indirect effects could occur based on the
                                                                                                              policies set.
Abt Associates, Inc.
                                  8-3
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
Section
51017
{1018
11021
TSCA Title IV. J402
§1021
TSCA Tille IV, (405
J1021
TSCA Title IV, 8406

11021
TSCA Title IV, §408
Affected Housing Slock or Entity
Federally supported inspections, risk assessments, interim controls and
abatements
Sale or lease of all housing stock constructed before 1978.
Persons offering to eliminate lead-based paint hazards.
Information on identifying and eliminating lead-based paint hazards.
Lead Hazard Information Pamphlet.

All executive, legislative and judicial branches of the federal
government having jurisdiction over property, or engaged in activities
that may result in a lead-based paint hazard
Relationship
§403 Identification used in Guidelines for
conducting federally supported lead-
based paint hazard reduction.
Requires notification to buyer of any
known lead-based paint hazards (as
identified by §403). Buyer has right to
perform inspection before being
obligated by contract for sale or lease.
Training and certification requirements
for all persons involved with identifying
and eliminating lead-baaed paint hazards
(as identified by §403).
1) Clearinghouse and hotline to provide
information on identifying, reducing and
eliminating lead-based paint hazards (as
identified by §403).
2) Establish protocols and performance
characteristics for products sold to
reduce or eliminate lead-bated paint
hazards (as identified by §403).
Required pamphlet to explain lead-based
paint hazards (at identified by §403) and
hazards.
All requirements in Lead-Based Paint
Hazard Reduction Act of 1992 shall
apply to all federal departments, agencies
and instrumentalities.
Small Entities Affected by §403
Hazard Levels
No significant direct or indirect effects
for small entities.
Small landlords could be burdened if the
market value of house decreased due to
the presence of lead; however if die
market reflects the higher value of a
lead free home once the market adjusts
there would be no differential burden
for small landlords.
These effects are covered under Section
402 Regulatory Flexibility Act.
No effect directly due to Section 403.
Information dissemination should have
no direct effect on small businesses.
i mo 11 covered under the Section 406
analysiB.

effect on small government!.
Abt Associates, Inc.
8-4
Draft. January 10, 1994

-------
 8.1.3  Data Availability

       Data on housing ownership and financial viability of landlords is available in proportion
 to the amount of Federal assistance given. In general, the four levels of housing ordered by
 decreasing amount of Federal assistance are:  Federally owned, local public housing authority
 owned, privately owned with public assistance, and privately owned. The information available
 on each of these levels is discussed below. Information on Federally  owned housing such as
 insured properties acquired through default by the Department  of Housing and  Urban
 Development (HUD), Resolution Trust Corporation, Veteran's Administration and Department
 of Defense is available.  However, since the Federal government is a large entity, the burden
 of the Title X requirements will not be considered here.  Public housing is owned by over 3,400
 local public housing authorities ranging in size from less than 100 units to over 9,000 units. The
 definition of small entity in this  regard may be determined by the financial  viability of the
 authority.  Data is available on the size of public housing authorities by units,  revenue and
 number of employees.  Privately owned and Federally assisted housing consists of multifamily
 rental properties under Sections 236 and 221(d)(3), project-based assistance for multifamily
 rentals under the Section 8 Program and Fanners Home Administration owner-occupied and
 rental programs under Sections 502, 504 and 515.  The total number  of units in HUD-based
 multifamily programs is perhaps 1.4 million. HUD can identify inventory and age but has little
 information on ownership except  whether the owner is a non-profit or profit entity.  Project
 income expense data is maintained by HUD  for some programs.  Title X makes testing and
 abatement  an eligible  expense for locally  administered  programs  for owner and rental
 rehabilitation;  however, the  number of rehabilitations  is not known.  The final housing
 category, private market rentals and sales are covered by two provisions of Title X.  Overall,
 quantitative data on privately owned housing is unavailable.  Large cities usually have property
 directories that list owners; however, they are not in a standard format and accessing the data
 could be difficult.  In cities with rent control, such as Los Angeles and the District of Columbia,
 the city directories could be searched by landlord to  locate all small landlords.  Unfortunately,
 this information is not compiled and would be resource-intensive to collect.

 8.1.4  Regulatory Options

       Classic options available to protect small business are possible under Section 403.
 Because Section 403  is a TSCA regulation, benefit-cost considerations are integral in setting the
 regulatory levels. Exemption of certain classes of small landlords from the provisions or relaxing
 the standards for small entities are two possibilities. Consideration of these options must include
 their effect on the overall goal of Section 403, which is to set health-based hazard levels and to
 the intent of the law, which is to protect the public health.

 8.2    PAPERWORK REDUCTION ACT ANALYSIS

       Setting of the lead hazard levels in paint, soil and  dust does not, of itself,  generate
 additional reporting or record keeping requirements. Thus there is no increase in burden or
 costs requiring analysis under the Paperwork Reduction Act.  Regulatory requirements by other
 Title IV sections (including sections 402 and 406) that rely on the hazard levels set under Section
 403 rules are evaluated separately in other regulatory impact analyses.
Abl Associates. Inc.                            8-5                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 8.3   TRADE IMPACTS ANALYSIS

       Section 403 of TSCA Title IV identifies lead hazard levels in paint, soil and dust for the
 puiposes of Title IV and the Residential Lead-Based Paint Hazard Reduction Act of 1992.
 The regulation requires certain abatement and notification activities to take place at these levels
• in  subsets of domestic housing as was  outlined in Section 1.2 Exhibit 1.1.  All the entities
 covered are domestic and there  is no anticipated direct effect on international trade.   Any
 indirect effects are expected to be negligible. Abatements are expected in housing other than
 those listed hi Exhibit 1.1 too. But these are all voluntary and more importantly domestic.

 8.4   ANALYSIS OF IMPACTS ON TECHNOLOGICAL INNOVATION

       No  analysis of technological innovation was  attempted at this time.   However, on
 examining the regulatory requirements, actions induced by the hazard levels that are set  under
 the regulation are likely to encourage innovation. Since the hazard levels may be used by states
 and localities as required levels of abatement, a larger lead testing and abatement market is likely
 to be created.  This could then  lead to greater competition and development of innovative testing
 or abatement methods.

       By setting numerical hazard levels, the type of innovation is limited to methods that allow
 abatement to below the standard and testing methods that can quantitatively detect levels  down
 to the identified hazard level.

 8.5   EQUITY IMPACTS ANALYSIS

       The Agency is concerned about whether there are disproportionate burdens on particular
categories of households or individuals as a  result of its actions.  Although the Section 403
hazard levels in lead-based paint, soil and dust have  not yet been established this analysis
investigates the equity impacts of four potential hazard levels.  The hazard levels are:

       •      XRF  ^ 6 mg/cm2  (maximum X-ray fluorescence reading in the housing unit).

       •      Both XRF ^ 6  mg/cm2 AND at least 10 per cent of the painted surface area is
             damaged.

       •      Dust lead concentration  £ 500 ppm.

       •      Soil lead concentration ^  500  ppm.

Lead hazards as defined above can occur in virtually all segments of the American housing
stock.  However,  even though lead-based paint hazards are widespread throughout the United
States, and affect every socioeconomic group,  the distribution of the hazards is not uniform with
respect to region of the country, age of housing stock, race or household income.  Lead hazards
are more common hi older, low-cost housing units in the North-East and Mid-West than in other
units. Because these housing units tend to be occupied by households at or below the poverty
level, including a disproportionate share of African-Americans,  these  sub-populations are
potentially exposed to relatively  more risks  than other sub-populations.  To the  extent that

Abt Associates, Inc.                          8-6                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 Section 403 results in more abatement of hazards in housing (including paint, dust and soil
 abatement), the segments of the U.S. population that are disproportionately exposed to the
 hazards are likely to receive a larger share of the risk reductions.  However, because most of
 the abatements covered by Title IV are voluntary, relatively wealthier households are more likely
 to proceed with the risk-reducing abatements.   This section  of the  report describes  the
 distribution of lead-based paint hazards in the housing stock, and considers the environmental
 equity implications of that distribution.

       The distributions, hi the U.S. housing stock, of the four potential hazard conditions listed
 above are estimated using data from the national survey of lead-based paint in housing sponsored
 by the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban  Development (HUD). The HUD survey was a
 national stratified sample of 284 privately owned, occupied housing units built before 1980.
 HUD developed weights for each observation, to create a weighted national sample representing
 the 77.1  million privately owned and occupied housing units.  The analysis in this section is
 based on the HUD estimates of the national pre-1980 housing stock.  These estimates are shown
 in Exhibit 8-2.
                                    EXHIBIT 8-2

                   National Prevalence of Lead-Based Paint Hazards




National Prevalence
in Pre-1980 Housing Stock



XRF £ 6
11%

XRF £ 6
and
> 10% Bad
Condition
4%


Dust
Concentration
S: 500 ppm
34%


Soil
Concentration
^ 500 ppm
11%

8.5.1  Age of Housing Stock

       In general,  lead-based paint hazards are more common in older housing stock.  Even
though lead  was not banned in household paint until 1978, the lead content of paint declined
after World War EL This is reflected in the distribution of the age of the housing stock that has
a lead-based paint  hazard as shown in Exhibit 8-3.  For example,  61  percent of the housing
stock with a maximum XRF reading of 6 mg/cm2 or more was built before 1930, even though
only 21 percent of the existing stock of pre-1980 housing units is that  old.   Shading indicates
a disproportionate prevalence of a potential hazard (i.e., the actual prevalence of a hazard in a
sub-group is at least 5 percent more than the sub-groups' share of the total national housing
stock). It is  important to realize that even though the older units are more likely to have a paint
hazard, hazards do exist in some housing units of all ages.
Abt Associates, Inc.
8-7
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                     EXHIBIT 8-3

          Distribution of Age of Housing Unit and Lead-Based Faint Conditions
Year Built
Pro 1930
1930 - '49
1950 - '65
1966 - '78
Total
Overall
Housing
Stock
Distribution
21%
13%
43%
22%
700%
XRF ;> 6
^•«*:;Si
14%
25%
-
700%
XRF Si 6
and
> 10% Bad
Condition
i^alB&S!
14%
47%
-
700%
Dust
Concentration
£: 500 ppm
$$$&»• .;!O%P'V'.' '.. ":
16%
23%
19%
700%
Soil
Concentration
^ 500 ppm
•&:£ 73i%1'" '"
7%
20%
-
700%
 8.5.2  Regional Distribution

       Because the North-East and Mid-West regions of the country tend to have relatively more
 older housing units than the South and West, these regions would be expected to have more paint
 hazards than regions with newer housing stock.  However, the hazards are even greater than
 would be expected if only housing age was considered. For example, of the national housing
 stock with maximum XRF readings of 6 mg/cm2 or more, 57 percent occur in the North-East
 region. Further, a total of 77 percent occur in the combined North-East and Mid-West regions;
 whereas these two regions have only 47 percent of the total pre-1980 housing stock. In contrast,
 the HUD survey found that in the West, which has 19 percent of the total housing stock,  high
 XRF readings occur in only 4% of all housing.  Exhibit 8-4 shows the regional distribution of
 the four lead-based paint hazards.
Abt Associates, Inc.
8-8
Draft. January 10, 1994

-------
                                     EXHIBIT 8-4
                  Regional Distribution of Lead-Based Faint Conditions
Region
MidWest
Noith-East
South
West
Total
Overall
Housing
Stock
Distribution
25%
22%
34%
19%
700%
XRF * 6
20%
**js*!«c#
19%
4%
700%
XRF £ 6
and
> 10% Bad
Condition

"^'iiitat^^
, /"jjjP»'x.sSI
17%
-
700%
Dust
Concentration
^ 500 ppm
jiSB^vv:
^SiST''""-
27%
12%
700%
Soil
Concentration
^ 500 ppm
.',3&»«&"v
13%
17%
15%
700%
 8.5.3  Cost of Housing

       The equity effects of uneven regional and housing age distribution of the four hazards
 are compounded by an uneven distribution of various demographic and socioeconomic sub-
 populations.  Although some of the nation's older housing stock is premium real estate, and
 commands a high market price, in general older housing units are less expensive than newer
 units.  Thus, the higher prevalence of the four hazards in the older housing stock is related to
 the fact that people living in lower cost housing are disproportionately exposed to the lead-based
 paint hazards. The prevalence of the four hazards by monthly housing cost (measured as either
 monthly rent or monthly mortgage payment to amortize a 10 percent mortgage in 30 years, not
 including taxes or insurance) is shown on Exhibit 8-5.  The least expensive  housing (less than
 $250 per month) has a disproportionately higher share of each of the four hazards than more
 expensive housing.

       Notice that the problem is not confined to low-cost housing.  Even the most expensive
 housing units have some prevalence of hazards, and comprise a disproportionately higher share
 of all units with high XRF readings.
Abt Associates, Inc.
8-9
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                     EXHIBIT 8-5

          Distribution of Monthly Housing Costs and Lead-Based Paint Hazards
Monthly
Housing
Cost
< $250
$250-$500
$500-$750
$750-1500
> $1500
Total
Overall
Housing
Stock
Distribution
17%
29%
18%
20%
16%
700%
XRF ^ 6
^.•'^t&^$
26%
13%
2%
^^ii^wsk
• --^rf *v»"~y™
100%
XRF Ss 6
and
> 10% Bad
Condition

8%

-
7%
700%
Dust
Concentration
£ 500 ppm

22%
15%
21%
18%
700%
Soil
Concentration
^ 500 ppm
^:32%t^
24%
23%
14%
7%
700%
 8.5.4 Income

       As would be expected, the relationship of lead-based paint hazards and income reflects
 that poorer people tend to live in the lower-cost houses, and thus bear a disproportionate share
 of the exposure to the four hazards. Exhibit 8-6 shows the distribution of household income and
 the hazards and that while the poorest people are far more likely to live in housing with a paint
 hazard, the hazards also occur for higher income households.

                                     EXHIBIT 8-6

       Distribution of Household Annual Income and Lead-Based Paint Conditions
Household
Annual
Income
< $10k
$10 - 20k
$20 - 30k
> $30k
NA
Total
Overall
Housing
Stock
Distribution
19%
16%
18%
40%
6%
700%
XRF 3» 6
42%
9%
16%
27%
5%
700%
XRF £ 6
and
> 10% Bad
Condition
52% ,
4%
..' -24%" ;:•••.-
20%
-
700%
Dust
Concentration
5: 500 ppm
" "
' . 28% Vr
12%
12%
'4S«L *
3%
700%
Soil
Concentration
^ 500 ppm
19%
9%
• »&#*•'
43%
5%
700%
Abt Associates, Inc.
8-10
                                                                   Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 8.5.5  Affordability
        The regulatory impact analysis has considered  abatement decision rules where each
 household chooses the type of abatement that maximizes its net benefits (both social and private
 benefits e.g., damages avoided by future children born into the current householders' abated
 house are included as  well as the  damages avoided by the  householders'  children).   No
 consideration has been made of whether the household could afford its optimal abatement choice.
 The following analysis compares an affordability threshold based on household income to the
 costs of the abatements chosen under the decision rules developed in this report.  The issues
 raised for public financing of abatements are also discussed.

 Affordability Measure and Income

       Affordability measures are typically based on either income or the value of the asset
 being  improved. For this analysis, we chose an income measure because of the short time
 (seven years) over which the benefit is accrued  and the availability of data. In the past,  the
 Agency has used a range of affordability measures.  Typical  measures for large scale capital
 projects are  1.8-2.1 percent of median household income in perpetuity (U.S. EPA, 1990).
 However, the case considered in this report is different because the benefits to a householders'
 child (and thus the duration of payment) occur over seven years. Therefore, we assumed that
 householders would be willing to spend as much as (5%) of their income annually if the duration
 were limited to  seven years.  The long term cost of capital, seven percent, is  used as  the
 discount rate.

         The distribution of household incomes from the Housing and Urban Development
 (HUD) study (Exhibit 8-6) served as the basis for this analysis. Two modifications were made
 to the distribution; first the home owners who had not reported  incomes were  redistributed in
 the same proportions as those who had reported, and second, the "greater than $30,000" income
 category was divided into two ranges of equal frequency (those between $30,000 and $50,000,
 and those greater than $50,000). Because $30,000 was the median income in 1990, the 75"1
 percentile income, $50,000, was chosen as the range limit (U.S. Department of Commerce,
 1992).  The resulting household income distribution is shown in  Exhibit 8-7.
                                    EXHIBITS-?

              Household Income Distribution and Affordability Threshold
Household Annual Income
< $10k
$10- <20k
$20- <30k
£30k - <50k
£50k
Overall Housing Stock
Distribution
21%
17%
19%
21.5%
21.5%
Affordability Threshold
$1,442
$4,325
$7,208
$8,650
$14,416
Abt Associates, Inc.
8-11
                                                                   Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
        Exhibit 8-7 also shows the affordable price (or threshold) associated with each income
 level; households are assumed to pay no more than the affordability threshold for an abatement.
 The affordable abatement cost was calculated from the midpoints of the income ranges except
 in the final two categories where the lower limits of the category ($30,000 and $50,000) were
 used. By using an affordability measure based on income, two further assumptions have been
 made implicitly.  First, we assume owners pay the cost of abatement and generate no increase
 in property value as a result, and  second, we assume that the cost of abatement is passed directly
 to renters. If property values increase as a result of abatement, we have underestimated the
 number of affordable abatements. Exhibit 8-8 compares the abatement costs, described in detail
 in Chapter 4, to the affordability thresholds.  Note that only nonrecurrent dust abatement is
 affordable at all  income levels  and only 18 of the 95 income/abatement combinations  are
 affordable.
Abt Associates, Inc.                           8-12                        Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                                                       EXHIBIT 8-8




                                             Affordable Abatement Scenarios by Income Level for Five Percent of Income

Abatement Scenario
High-end Paint
Low-end Paint
High-end Soil
>2000 ppm and exterior paint
£2000 ppm and exterior painl
>2000 ppm and no exterior paint
£2000 ppm and no exterior paint
Low-end Soil
Recurrent Dust
Nonrecurrent Dust
High-end Paint and High-end Soil
>2000 ppm and exterior paint
£2000 ppm and exterior paint
>2000 ppm and no exterior paint
£2000 ppm and no exterior paint
High-end Paint and Low-end Soil
Low-end Paint and High-end Soil
>2000 ppm and exterior painl
£2000 ppm and exterior paint
>2000 ppm and no exterior paint
£2000 ppm and no exterior paint
f 4|W-fnd P"int And 1 4ia/^nH SAI|
Abatement Unit Cort
$10.500
$2.750

$21.412
$12,998
$16.412
$7.998
$7.493
$7.676
$750

$31.912
$23.498
$26.912
$18,498
$17.993

$24,162
$15.748
$19,162
$10.748
tin 74*
1 Income
Affordability























$20K
$4,325


X







X












$20->$30K
$7.208










X












$30->$50K
$8,650























>$50K
$14,416























Abt Associates, Inc.
8-13
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 Results

        Exhibit 8-9 shows the number of affordable abatements by scenario and decision rule
 over the fifty year model lifetime.  (The nine decision rules were explained in Chapter 6.) As
 explained in Chapter 3, each abatement decision represents a portion of the housing stock. To
 determine the number of unaffordable abatements we compared the five affordability thresholds
 in proportion to their frequency in the housing stock distribution (as shown in Exhibit 8-7) to
 the cost of the abatement  chosen.  Those abatements costing more  than the affordability
 threshold were considered unaffordable.

        The percent of optimal abatements that are affordable range from over 99 percent in the
 voluntary optimum decision rule to 43 percent for rules where doing only non-recurrent dust
 abatement, the most affordable  scenario, does not satisfy the decision  rule constraints.   The
 affordability by abatement type (in Exhibit 8-9) shows where the majority of the unaffordable
 abatements are for each decision rule.   The constraint of abating all nonintact paint combined
 with the relatively high cost of paint abatement causes these categories (high-end paint, low-end
 paint, high-end paint and high-end soil,  low-end paint and low-end soil,  and low-end paint and
 high-end soil) to account for the majority of the unaffordable abatements.

        For every decision rule but the voluntary optimum, the total net benefits of the affordable
 abatements are higher than  the total net benefits of all abatements.  This means  that for all
 decision rules other than the voluntary optimum, many of those who could not afford to abate
 had individual negative net benefits. For example, the total net benefit for a decision rule based
 on 1,200 ppm dust are $3.3 billion when affordability is ignored. Once affordability thresholds
 are imposed, the net benefits rise to $15.6 billion.  In the  voluntary optimum, however,
 individual benefits always exceed individual costs.  Thus, eliminating any households because
 they cannot afford to abate will reduce the net benefits.

        From a social welfare perspective, only those homes  with positive net benefits warrant
 abatement.   Those  households who cannot afford to abate may be publicly funded.   The
 following discussion characterizes the number and value of the abatements that would qualify
 for assistance under this perspective.  First, Exhibit 8-10 shows the number of unaffordable
 abatements which have positive net benefits, the majority of which are low soil abatements.  The
 total net benefits correspondingly range from $454 to $680 million or about $33 million to $49
 million annually at a seven percent discount rate.  The total cost,  over the fifty year model
 lifetime, of subsidizing these abatements ranges from $622 million for the paint condition  only
 to  almost $2 billion for the  three media  constrained decision  rule.   This translates  into
 approximately $45 million to $145 million annually.1

       If all the unaffordable abatements were funded, whether they  result  in positive net
 benefits or not, the cost range would be $1.1  billion to $20.8 billion,  which is equivalent to $80
       The numbers presented represent an upper bound by subsidizing the total cost of the abatement. If each
household paid to its affordability threshold, the total cost over 50 years would range from $387 million to $1.3
billion. This translates into $28 million to $94 million annually.

Abt Associates, Inc.                           8-14                        Draft, January 10. 1994

-------
 million to $1.5 billion annually.3  However, the range of net benefits would fall significantly.
 The new range is minus $12.7 billion to positive $454 million, which, on an annual basis, is
 minus $920 million to positive $33 million.

        Note that this analysis only considers the affordability of the optimal abatement chosen
 based on maximizing net benefits. A more in-depth analysis could introduce an affordability
 constraint when the optimal abatement is being chosen, limiting the abatement  choices to those
 below an affordability threshold.  This would decrease the total benefits but could also reduce
 costs.  Finally, the cost of testing for lead has not been included.  These costs can be substantial,
 $713 per unit, if all media are tested.  Obviously, the number of unaffordable abatements would
 increase if the testing costs were added.

        Funding for lead abatements (including inspection) is formalized and authorized at $125
 million for  1993 and $250 million for 1994 according to Title X, Section 1011.  Additional
 funds may be available through subsequent Appropriations Acts. This level of funding compares
 favorably with the amount needed to subsidize unaffordable abatements that result in positive net
 benefits.  However, the funding may  not  be adequate to subsidize all unaffordable abatements
 induced by certain decision rules.  Further, the funding is only appropriated over two years and
 the model project lifetime is fifty years.   (Thus the same level of funding would have to be
 appropriated each year for the next fifty years.) The case presented here does  not consider all
 the possible  sources of funds for residential lead abatement.  States and localities have a history
 of funding such projects.  It may  be possible to extend the funds by providing concessionary
 loans as Massachusetts has done. In this way, abatements can  be performed on  loans at
 subsidized interest rates but at a lower cost to  government than a grant program.  The case
 presented  here represents  an upper  bound estimate  of the annual cost  to  government of
 subsidizing abatements.
       These values represent the upper bound by subsidizing the total cost of the abatement. The total cost over
SO years would range from $780 million to $12.7 billion equivalent to $56 million to $920 million annually if each
household paid an amount equal to its affordability value.

Abt Associates, Inc.                            8-15                        Draft. January 10. 1994

-------
                                                                 EXHIBIT 8-9

              Affordability (at Five Percent of Income) of Abatement Choices for Five Alternative Decision Rules
Decision Rules
'•
2.
3.
4.
5.
Voluntary
Ootimum
Paint Condition
Only
Single
Medium
Plus
Condition
2-Media
Plus
Condition
3a.
3b.
3c.
4a.
4b.
4c.
3-Media Plus
Condition
Soil
(ppm)
-
•
2.300
~
*
2,300
2,300
~
2,300
Dust
(ppm)
-
•
-
1,200
~
1,200
™
1,200
1,200
Paint
(XRF,
mg/cm1)
-
•
-
*
20
•
20
20
20
Nonintacl Paint
Abatement
Recommended
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Total Net
Benefits
Exclusive ol
Testing
Costs
($ millions)
34,294
-17,349
-17.159
3,299
-17.631
3,017
-17,440
3,017
2,736
Total
Affordable
Abatements
(1000s)
(Percent of
Total)
44,832
99.26%
3,089
43.74%
3,488
43.23%
11,169
71.59%
3,134
43.75% "
11,391
70.33%
3,533
43.24%
11,213
71.41%
11,435
70 17%
Total Net
Benefits of
Affordable
Abatements
Exclusive
of Testing
Costa ($
millions)
33,840
•4,834
-4,711
15,635
-4,921
15,554
-4,798
15,548
15,468
Number and Percent of Total Homeowners with Unaffordable Abatements by
Type • (1000s)
HP

3,265
46%
3,265
40%
3,286
21%
3.313
46%
3.286
20%
3,313
41%
3,334
21%
3,334
20%
LP
4
0.01%
583
8%
570
7%
573
4%
591
8%
561
3%
579
7%
582
4%
570
3%
HS



42
0.27%
0
42
0.26%

42
0.27%
42
0.26%
LS
329
0.73%

573
7%
234
2%

573
4%
573
7%
234
1.49%
573
4%
RD



158
1%

158
1%

158
1%
158
1%
HP/HS









HP/LS

114
2%
114
1%
114
1%
114
2%
114
1%
114
1%
114
1%
114
LP/HS



14
0.09%

14
0.09%

14
0.09%
14
LP/LS

12
0.17%
58
1%
12
0.08%
12
0.17%
58
0.36%
58
0.71%
12
0.08%
58
NRD
0
Oft


0
0%

0
0%

0
0%
0
'Abatement Codes: High Paint(HP); Low Paint(LP); High Soil(HS); Low Soil(LS); Recurrent Dust (RD); High Paint and High Soil(HP/HS); High Paint and Low Soil(HP/LS); Low Paint and High
Soil (LP/HS); Low Paint and Low Soil (LP/LS); Nonrecurrent Dust (NRD). The abatement activities, wen described in Exhibits 4.1-4.6.
Abt Associates, Inc.
8-16
Draft. January 10, 1994

-------
                                                                            EXHIBIT 8-10

                    AITordabilily (at Fire Percent of Income) of Abatement Chokes for Households with Positive Net Benefits for Five AltematiTe Decision Rules
Decision Rules
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
Voluntary
Ootimum
Paint Condition
Only
Single
Medium
Plus
Condition
2-Media
Plus
Condition
3a.
3b.
3c.
4a.
4b.
4c.
3-Media Plus
Condition
Soil
(ppm)
-
•
2.300
-
-
2.300
2,300
~
2.300
Dust
(ppm)
-
•
•
1,200
•
1,200
-
1,200
1.200
Paint
(XRF.
ing/cm1)
-
•
•
-
20
•
20
20
20
Nonintact Paint
Abatement
Recommended
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Total Net
Benefits of
Unaffordable
Abatements
with Positive
Net Benefits
Exclusive of
Testing Costs
($ millions)
454
226
642
532
226
680
642
532
680
Total Costs of
Unaffordable
Abatements
with Positive
Net Benefits
Exclusive of
Testing Costs
($ millions)
1.141
622
1,679
1,728
622
1,976
1.679
1,728
1.976
Total Costs
of
Unaffordable
Abatements

1,141
17,545
19,726
19,223
17.787
20,595
19,968
19,464
20.837
Number and Percent of Total Homeowners with Unaffordable Abatements by
Type* (1000s)
HP

104
1.47%
104
1.29%
104
0.67%
104
1.45%
104
0.64%
104
1.27%
104
0.66%
104
064%
LP
4
0.01%
48
0.69%
48
0.60%
43
0.27%
48
0.68%
43
0.26%
48
0.59%
43
0.27%
43
0.26%
HS



42
0.27%

42
0.26%

42
0.27%
42
0.26%
LS
329
0.73%

306
4%
234
1.50%

306
1.89%
306
3.75%
234
1.49%
306
1 88%
RD



42
0.27%

42
0.26%

42
0.27%
42
0.26%
HP/HS









HP/LS

0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
LP/H
S



0
0%

0
0%

0
0%
0
0%
LP/LS

12
0.17%
12
0.15%
12
0.08%
12
0.17%
12
0.08%
12
0.15%
12
0.08%
12
008%
NRD
0
0%


0
0%

0
0%

0
0%
0
0%
•Abatement Codes: High Paint(HP); Low Painl(LP); High Soil(HS); Low Soil(LS); Recurrent Dust (RD); High Paint and High Soil(HP/HS); High Paint and Low Soil(HP/LS); Low Paint and High
Soil (LP/HS); Low Paint and Low Soil (LP/LS); Nonrecurrent Dust (NRD). The abatement activities wen described in Exhibits 4.1-4.6.
Abt Associates, Inc.
8-17
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 Alternative Threshold Analysis

       Exhibit 8-11 shows which abatements are affordable if two percent of income over seven
 years is used as the affordability threshold. The two percent level corresponds to past EPA
 analysis although the period, seven years, is shorter as described above (U.S.EPA, 1990). Only
 seven of the 95 income/abatement combinations are affordable.  As expected, the percent of
 affordable abatements decreases for each decision rule when compared  to the five percent
 affordability  threshold.  (See Exhibit 8-12.)  Only 78 percent of the abatements are affordable
 under  the voluntary optimum; this  falls  to less than 25 percent for decision rules where
 nonrecurrent dust abatement is not an option.  Exhibit 8-13 shows that the total cost over fifty
 years of subsidizing all  households  below the threshold which  have positive individual  net
 benefits is $825 million  to $4.4 billion or $60 to $319 million annually discounted at seven
 percent.  Corresponding net benefits are $334 million to $7.8 billion or $24 to $565 million
 annually. This alternative analysis shows the importance of the affordability threshold chosen
 to the quantity of abatements that are considered unaffordable.
Abi Associates, Inc.                           8-18                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                                                      EXHIBIT 8-11
                                             Affordable Abatement Scenarios by Income Level for Two Percent of Income

Abatement Scenario
High-end Paint
Low-end Paint
High-end Soil
>2000 ppm and exterior paint
£2000 ppm and exterior paint
>2000 ppm and no exterior paint
£2000 ppm and no exterior paint
Low-end Soil
Recurrent Oust
Nonrecurrent Dust
High-end Paint and High-end Soil
>2000 ppm and exterior paint
£2000 ppm and exterior paint
>2000 ppm and no exterior paint
£2000 ppm and no exterior paint
High-end Paint and Low-end Soil
Low-end Paint and High-end Soil
>2000 ppm and exterior paint
£2000 ppm and exterior paint
>2000 ppm and no exterior paint
£2000 ppm and no exterior paint
Isra/wtiiH Paint and lnw-»nrt Sail

Abatement Unit Cost
$10,500
$2,750

$21.412
$12,998
$16,412
$7.998
$7,493
$7,676
$750

$31,912
$23,498
$26,912
$18.498
$17,993

$24.162
$15,748
$19,162
$10,748
tin 741
Income
AfTordability
Threshold























<$10K
$577























$10->$20K
$1,730










X












$20->$30K
$2.883


X







X












$30->$50K
$3,460























>S50K
$5.767























Abt Associates, Inc.
8-19
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
                                                                            EXHIBIT 8-12

                                       AfTordabilily (al Two Percent of Income) of Abatement Choices for Five Altematife Decision Rules

1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
Decision Rules
Voluntary
Ootimum
Paint Condition
Only
Single
Medium
Plus
Condition
2-Media
Plus
Condition
3a.
3h
3c.
4a.
4b.
4c.
3-Media Plus
Condition
Soil
(ppm)
-
"
2,300
•
"
2.300
2.300
"
2.300
Dust
(ppm)
-
•
•
1.200
~
1.200
"
1,200
1,200
Paint
(XRF.
ing/cm1)
-
•
~
•
20
'
20
20
20
Noninlacl Paint
Abatement
Recommended
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Total Net
Benefits
Exclusive of
Testing
Costs
($ millions)
34.294
-17.349
-17.159
3.299
-17.631
3.017
-17,440
3.017
2,736
Total
Affordable
Abatements
(1000s)
(Percent of
Total)
35,221
77.98%
1.720
24.35%
1,684
20.87%
7.837
50.23%
1.745
2435%
7.801
48.16%
1,708
20.91%
7,862
50.07%
7.825
48 02%
Total Net
Benefits of
Affordable
Abatements
Exclusive
of Testing
Costs ($
millions)
26,463
-1.278
-1,248
14.767
-1.306
14.797
-1.276
14,739
14,769
Number and Percent of Total Homeowners with Unaffordable Abatements by Type*
(1000s)
HP

4,160
59%
4,160
52%
4.186
27%
4.221
59%
4,186
26%
4,221
52%
4.247
27%
4,247
26%
LP
8
0.02%
1,054
15%
1,032
13%
1.038
7%
1,069
15%
1,015
6%
1,047
13%
1,053
7%
1,031
6%
HS



74
0.47%
0
74
0.46%

74
0.47%
74
0 45%
LS
577
1.28%

1,006
12%
411
3%

1,006
6%
1,006
12%
411
2.62%
1,006
6%
RD



276
2%

276
2%

276
2%
276
2%
HP/HS









HP/LS

114
2%
114
1%
114
1%
114
2%
114
1%
114
1%
114
1%
114
1 %
LP/HS



18
0.11%

18
0.11%

18
0.11%
18
LP/LS

16
0.22%
74
1%
16
0.10%
16
0.22%
74
0.46%
74
0.91%
16
0.10%
74
NRD
9,359
20.72%


1,633
10.47%

1,633
10.08%

1,633
10.40%
1,633
•Abatement Codes: High Paint(HP); Low Paint(LP); High Soil(HS); Low Soil(LS); Recurrent Dust (RD); High Paint and High Soil(HP/HS); High Paint and Low Soil(HP/LS); Low Paint and
High Soil (LP/HS); Low Paint and Low Soil (LP/LS); Nonrecurrent Dust (NRD).  The abatement activities were described in Exhibits 4.1-4.6.
Abt Associates, Inc.
8-20
Draft. January 10, 1994

-------
                                                                            EXHIBIT 8-13

                    Affordability (at Two Percent of Income) of Abatement Chokes for Households with PositiTe Net Benefits for Five Alternatta Decision Rules
Decision Rules
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
Voluntary
Optimum
Paint Condition
Only
Single
Medium
Plui
Condition
2-Media
Plui
Condition
3a.
3b.
3c.
4a.
4b.
4c.
3-Media Plus
Condition
Soil
(ppm)
-
•
2,300
•
~
2.300
2,300
•
2,300
Dust
(ppm)
-
•
-
1,200
•
1.200
•
1.200
1.200
Paint
(XRF.
mg/cm*)
-
•
•
-
20
•
20
20
20
Nonintact Paint
Abatement
Recommended
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Tola! Net
Benefits of
Unaffbrdable
Abatements
with Positive
Net Benefits
Exclusive of
Testing Costs
($ millions)
7,831
334
1.065
5,141
334
5,401
1,065
5,141
5,401
Total Costs of
Unaflbrdable
Abatements
with Positive
Net Benefits
Exclusive of
Testing Costs
($ millions)
4,496
825
2,680
3,203
825
3,638
2,680
3.203
3.638
Total Costs
of
Unaffoidable
Abatements
Threshold ($
million)
4,496
22,487
26,210
25,801
22.801
28,104
26,524
26.115
28,418
Number and Percent of Total Homeowners with Unaffbrdable Abatements by
Type* (1000s)
HP

132
1.87%
132
1.64%
132
0.85%
132
0.00%
132
0.82%
132
1.62%
132
0.84%
132
0 81%
LP
8
0.02%
88
1.24%
88
1.09%
77
0.50%
88
0.00%
77
0.48%
88
1.07%
77
0.49%
77
0 47%
HS



74
0.47%

74
0.46%

74
0.47%
74
0 45*
LS
577
1.28%

537
6.65%
411
2.63%

537
3.32%
537
6.57%
411
2.62%
537
3 29%
RD



74
0.47%

74
0.46%

74
0.47%
74
0 45%
HP/HS









HP/LS

0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
0
0%
LP/HS



0
0%

0
0%

0
0%
0
0%
LP/LS

16
0.22%
16
0.19%
16
0.10%
16
0.22%
16
0.10%
16
0.19%
16
0.10%
16
0 10%
NRD
9,359
21%


1,591
10%

1.591
10%

1.591
10%
1,591
10%
•Abatement Codes: High Paint(HP); Low Paint(LP); High Soil(HS); Low Soil(LS); Recurrent Dust (RD); High Paint and High Soil(HP/HS); High Paint and Low Soil(HP/LS); Low Paint and High
Soil (LP/HS); Low Paint and Low Soil (LP/LS); Nonrecurrent Dust (NRD). The abatement activities were described in Exhibits 4.1-4.6.
Abt Associates, Inc.
8-21
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 8.5.6  Race

       Lead-based paint hazards are more likely to affect African-Americans than other racial
 sub-populations.  This is a result of both the larger African-American share of the population
 in the North-East and Mid-West, and of the higher poverty rate for African-Americans. Exhibit
 8-14 shows the distribution of the hazards by race. (Race is defined as the stated race of the
 youngest person in the household.)

                                    EXHIBIT 8-14

    Distribution of Household Racial Composition and Lead-Based Paint Conditions


Race

African-
American
Hispanic
White
Other
Total
Overall
Housing
Stock
Distribution
9%

7%
78%
7%
700%



XRF > 6
.-'Oat-
~ff •• ' '. • > •
3%
66%
2%
700%
XRF2t 6
and
> 10% Bad
Condition
:*j$j|Njj. $
"• ' ^S'*^
4%
44%
-
700%

Dust
Concentration
^ 500 ppm
^'*xt$jjjj^^
^...,.-^-:^:.. -j
4%
71%
11%
700%

Soil
Concentration
^ 500 ppm
11%

3%
79%
7%
700%
8.5.7  Other Socioeconomic Variables

       The prevalence of lead-based paint hazards based on other socioeconomic variables does
not show as dramatic a disproportionate prevalence as the region, income and race variables.
Exhibit 8-15 shows the prevalence for the following variables:  ownership, presence of children,
presence of elderly. A summary of this dispropoitionality is as follows:
             Ownership: rental units are somewhat more likely to have high XRF readings.

             Presence of children (6 years old or less):  there is no disproportionate prevalence
             of lead-based paint hazards among units with young children.

             Elderly (defined as at least one person over the age  of 65 living in the unit): no
             overall pattern of disproportionate prevalence, but units including elderly people
             are somewhat less likely to have  both high XRF readings  and bad  paint
             conditions.
Abt Associates, Inc.
8-22
Draft. January 10, 1994

-------
                                    EXHIBIT 8-15

              Distribution of Other Household Demographic Characteristics
                            and Lead-Based Fault Conditions

Ownership
Rent
Own
Children
£ 6 Years
Present?
No
Yes
Adult
> 65 Years
Present?
No
Yes
Overall
Housing
Stock
Distribution
XRF ;> 6
XRF £ 6
and
> 10% Bad
Condition
Dust
Concentration
£ 500 ppm
Soil
Concentration
£ 500 ppm

35%
65%
- '4i*-Ki
55%
"wf^V-ijMS™":- %-^V •
59%
31%
69%
36%
64%

82%
18%
79%
21%
86%
14%
85%
15%
78%
22%

76%
24%
77%
23%
100%
-
78%
22%
80%
20%
Abt Associates, Inc.
8-23
Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
 8.5.8  Data Limitations

       The U.S. Housing and Urban Development survey provides the best nationwide data for correlating
 socioeconomic information and residential housing lead levels. However, the data are limited.  Because only
 284 privately owned homes were sampled the actual number of homes in the various socioeconomic strata of
 interest is small.  The confidence intervals are thus correspondingly large. While the data may show trends,
 the small sample size indicates caution should be used in interpreting the results.

 8.5.9  Environmental Equity Conclusions

       Existing lead-based paint hazards are a risk to all segments of our population living in pre-1980 housing,
 and local, state and federal efforts to reduce the risks of lead-based paint must extend to all potentially affected
 parties.  However, the HUD survey does indicate that some segments of our society are at relatively greater
 risk than others.  In particular, the residents of older, low cost housing are exposed to a disproportionately
 greater share of lead potential hazard than other housing units.  The housing stock in the North-East (and to
 some extent the Mid-West) includes a larger share of such units than other regions, creating a regional inequity
 in the prevalence  of the problem.  Because poorer people  usually occupy low-cost housing, the hazards
 disproportionately fall on lower income sub-populations (especially households living in poverty, with annual
 incomes below $10,000), creating an income inequity. Finally, the relatively larger share of African-Americans
 in the lower income groups results in racial inequity.

       Although the baseline risks  from lead-based paint  disproportionately fall on poorer sub-populations,
 abatement may well be more likely to occur in housing units occupied by wealthier households.  Most of the
 abatements under the Lead-Based Paint Hazard Reduction Act will be voluntary, and wealthier households are
 more likely to have the means to abate an existing problem in their home, or avoid moving into a housing unit
 with a known lead-based paint hazard.  Thus even though a national strategy of eliminating lead-based paint
 risks targets a problem affecting a greater share of poor  households and African-Americans,  the impact of
 income on  the ability to undertake voluntary  abatements may result in a more inequitable distribution of  the
 risks in the future.

       As shown in Section 8.S.S the ability  to afford abatements may have a serious impact on the number
of abatements undertaken voluntarily.  In addition, when the affordable abatements are considered alone the
net benefits rise in all but the voluntary optimum decision rule.  This  implies that not all  unaffordable
abatements may be worth subsidizing because some have  negative net benefits.   However, subsidizing only
those with positive net benefits raises a fairness issue, since many of the affordable abatements induced by the
decision rule had negative net benefits yet presumably were paid for privately by households.   Should those
who cannot afford abatements  be given the same treatment?  In practice, can the homes with positive and
negative net benefits be identified in a cost effective manner?  Finally, significant funds,  sustained over time,
will be required to subsidize even those unaffordable abatements which have net benefits greater than zero.
      Abt Associates, Inc.                          8-24                       Draft, January 10, 1994

-------
8.6

U.S. Environmental Protection  Agency, 1990. (U.S.  EPA,  1990)   "National Characterization of Small
Communities: The Ability to Finance Wastewater Construction Projects", April.

U.S. Department of Commerce, 1992.  (U.S. Department of Commerce, 1992)  "Statistical Abstract of the
United States, 1992" U. S Government  Printing Office.
      Abt Associates. Inc.                         8-25                      Draft, January 10. 1994

-------