REGULATORY IMPACT ANALYSIS: BENEFITS AND COSTS OF PROPOSED NATIONAL PRIMARY DRINKING WATER REGULATIONS FOR INORGANIC CHEMICALS PREPARED FOR: Environmental Protection Agency Office of Drinking Water Washington, D.C. 20460 PREPARED BY: Wade Miller Associates, Inc. 1911 North Fort Myer Drive Arlington, VA 22209 PREPARED UNDER: EPA Contract No. 68-03-3348 Work Assignment No. 2-12 Under Subcontract to The Cadmus Group Mr. Brian Rourke, Project Officer Mr. Carl Kessler, Technical Project Monitor ------- ------- TABLE OF CONTENTS PAGE 1. Introduction and Summary !_! 1.1 Introduction 2.-1 1.2 Problem Definition ' ^.^ 1.3 Market Imperfections, The Need for Federal Regulation, and Consideration of Regulatory Alternatives !_3 1.4 Assessment of Total Costs 1-3 1.5 Assessment of Benefits 1_5 1.6 Regulatory Flexibility, and Paperwork Reduc- tion Analyses 1-6 1.7 Summary of Costs and Benefits 1-7 2. Problem Definition 2-i 2.1 Introduction 2-i 2.2 Health Effects 2_4 2.3 Occurrence 2-5 2.4 Treatment Technologies 2-14 2.5 Analytical Methods 2-18 3. Market Imperfections, The Need for Federal Regula- tion, and Consideration of Regulatory Alternatives 3-1 3.1 Introduction 3_! 3.2 The Nature of the Imperfections 3-2 3.3 The Need for Federal Regulation 3-6 3.4 Consideration of Regulatory Alternatives 3-10 ------- TABLE OF CONTEWTS (Continued) PAGE 4. Assessment of Costs 4-1 4.1 Introduction 4-1 4.2 Major Assumptions Used in Cost Estimates 4-1 4.3 Treatment Costs for lOCs 4-2 4.4 Waste Disposal Costs 4-10 4.5 Uncertainty in Estimates of National Costs 4-10 4.6 Monitoring Costs 4-15 4.7 Costs to State Programs 4-28 5. Assessment of Benefits 5-1 5.1 “Damages Avoided” versus Total Benefits 5—1 5.2 Benefits of a Margin of Safety 5-1 5.3 Induced Efficiency Improvements in the Water Industry 5-3 5.3 Aggregate Analysis of Health Benefits 5-4 6. Regulatory Flexibility Analysis and Paperwork Reduction Analysis 6-1 6.1 Regulatory Flexibility Analysis 6-]. 6.2 Paperwork Reduction Analysis 6-7 7. Summary of Costs, Benefits, and Uncertainty 7-1 7.1 Total Incremental National Costs 7-]. 7.2 Total Incremental National Benefits 7-4 ------- LIST OF EXHIBITS EXHIBIT PAGE 1-1 Incremental Cost of IOC Rule at Proposed MCL Alternatives 1-4 1-2 Incremental Impacts of Proposed IOC Reg- ulations At Proposed Alternatives 1-8 2—1 Summary of Health Effects for Inorganic Chemicals 2-2 2—2 General Form of Delta Log - Normal Distri- bution 2-7 2-3 Standardized Numbers of Public Water Sys- tems and Populations Served by Source arid Size Categories 2-9 2—4 Conversion of Occurrence Data to Standard- ized System Size Categories (by Population Served) 2-10 2-5 Community Water Systems with bC Contamina- tion Greater Than or Equal to Current MCLs 2-11 2—6 Summary of Co-Occurrence in All Community Water Systems 2-13 2-7 lOCs for Which Conventional Treatment is Effective (Greater than 70 Percent Removal) 2-15 2-8 lOCs for Which Lime Softening is Effective Treatment (Greater than 90 Percent Removal) 2—16 2—9 lOCs for Which Ion Exchange Treatment is Effective (Greater than 90 Percent Removal) 2-16 2—10 Analytical Methods for lOCs 2—19 3—1 Annual Family Bills for Selected Utilities 1952—1984 - and - Percent of Median Family Income Spent on Selected Utilities 1952—1984 3—3 3-2 MCL Alternative for lOCs (ug/l) 3-13 ------- LIST OF EXHIBITS (Continued) EXHIBIT PAGE 4-1 FRDS IOC Violations in Community Water Systems Serving More than 50,000 Persons 4-3 4—2 Estimated Treatment and Waste Disposal Costs at Most Stringent MCL Alternatives 4-4 4—3 Estimated Treatment and Waste Disposal Costs at Proposed MCL Alternatives 4-7 4—4 Standard Errors of Independent Variables in bC Cost Calculation (As a Percent of Mean Values) 4—14 4-5 Standard Errors in Compliance Cost Estimates (As Decimal Fractions of Mean Values) 4-15 4-6 Average Annual Monitoring Costs of Proposed IOC Regulations (In Millions of 1986 Dollars) 4-16 4-7 Inorganic Chemicals: Proposed Monitoring Requirements 4-19 4-8 Asbestos: Proposed Monitoring Requirements 4-22 4-9 Nitrate/Nitrite: Proposed Monitoring Re- quireinents 4-23 4—10 Analytical Cost Assumptions —— lOCs 4-27 5-1 Size Distribution of Community Water Systems 5-6 5-2 Reduction in Population Exposed to Inorganic Chemicals at Most Stringent MCL Alternative (In Thousands) 5-8 5-3 Reduction in Population Exposed to Inorganic Chemicals at Preferred MCLJ Alternatives (In Thousands) 5-9 5-4 Estimated Population Exposed (Millions) to Various Concentrations of Asbestos in Community Drinking Water Systems 5-10 5-5 Estimated Baseline Cancer Cases Due to Asbestos Contamination in Community Drinking Water Systems 5-12 ------- LIST OF EXHIBITS (Continued) EXHIBIT PAGE 6-]. Estimated Number of Small Entities Affected by Proposed IOC Rule 6-4 6-2 Production Cost Increase (Macro—Level Analysis) 6-5 6-3 Production Cost Increase by System Size Category (Micro-Level Analysis) 6-6 7-1 Estimated Impact of Regulating lOCs at Most Stringent MCL Alternatives 7-2 7-2 Estimated Impact of Regulating lOCs at Proposed MCL Alternatives 7-3 ------- 1. INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY 1.1 Introduction This report contains an analysis of the costs and benefits of controlling inorganic chemical contaminants (lOCs) in drinking water through the promulgation of regulations for maximum contam- inant level goals (MCLGs) and maximum contaminant levels (MCLs). This regulatory impact analysis (RIA) was prepared in accordance with Executive Order 12291 which requires that the costs and bene- fits of all major rules be examined and compared. The major topical areas covered in this RIA are as follows: o Problem Definition: o Market Imperfections, the Need for Federal Regulation, and Consideration of Regulatory Alternatives; o Assessment of Total Costs; o Assessment of Benefits; o Regulatory Flexibility and Paperwork Reduction Analyses; and, o A Summary of Costs and Benefits. This initial chapter contains a summary of results. Detailed analyses of costs and benefits are included in Chapters 4 and 5. 1.2 Problem Definition In accordance with the requirements of the Safe Drinking Water Act Amendments of 1986 (SDWA) EPA is developing new or revised drinking water regulations for the following lOCs: asbestos, bar- ium, cadmium, chromium, mercury, nitrate, nitrite, and selenium. Available evidence suggests that adverse health effects attributable to bC exposure generally involve acute or chronic sub-lethal endpoints of toxicity. The Agency has developed long- term drinking water equivalent levels (DWELs) which serve as the basis for determining maximum contaminant level goals (MCLCs) for lOCs. Three contaminants evaluated under this proposal have also exhibited evidence carcinogenic effects; these are cadmium, chrom- ium, and asbestos. The strength of evidence of carcinogenicity yj drinkin water ex osure is not considered significant by the Agency for these contaminants however. Therefore, MCLG5 are being 1—1 ------- proposed as though they had limited or no evidence of carcinogenicity as drinking water contaminants. Ma-icr Assumptions Used in Analysis Three critical assumptions serve as the basis for the impacts estimated in this analysis. First, it is necessary to avoid misallocation of impacts of regulations currently in place to those resulting from revised regulations. Because all contaminants except asbestos and nitrite are currently regulated, it was assumed that no impacts would be attributable to revised MCLs set equal to or greater than those currently in place. At the most stringent (i.e., lowest) MCL alternatives, an assessment of net incremental cost impacts is necessary for all lOCs evaluated (recognizing that significant co-occurrence may be involved at such low concentrations). At “preferred” MCL alter- natives (i.e., those corresponding most closely with proposed MCLGs), it is estimated that net incremental costs will result for only cadmium. The second major assumption concerns the consolidation of occurrence data across different system size categories. In developing estimates of occurrence probabilities, raw survey data from several size categories were typically combined and analyzed as a group. This procedure resulted in invariant occurrence probabilities across system size categories for most lOCs. However, because the estimates are based on sampling data from finished water, and since systems serving greater than 50,000 persons generally have more effective treatment processes, more comprehensive monitoring, and a higher level of operator expertise in place, it was assumed that bC occurrence in large systems is probably negligible compared to that in smaller systems. Finally, occurrence data on mercury in surface water systems is subject to extreme uncertainty. For this reason, estimates which include mercury occurrence as calculated, as well as esti- mates using the assumption that mercury occurrence is zero are presented in the analysis. The phenomenon of co-occurrence was evaluated based on combined probabilities of occurrence of individual contaminants at the preferred MCLs. It was estimated that approximately one percent of affected systems have occurrence of two contaminants. On this basis, it was assumed that an even smaller number of systems would be likely to have simultaneous occurrence of three or more contaminants. Based on these results, it was assumed that the degree of co-occurrence of lOCs (and resulting effects on the aggregate national impacts) is negligible and no attempt was made to adjust the calculations at the proposed MCLs. 1—2 ------- Under the assumptions discussed above, it is estimated that the incremental impacts of the revised regulations will affect approximately 192 coriununity and non-transient, non-community water systems. This translates into a national population exposure estimate of 170,000 persons. 1.3 Market Imperfections, The Need for Federal Recrulatjon, and Consideration of Req-ulatory Alternatives EPA has proposed the IOC regulations in accordance with the requirements of the SDWA Amendments of 1986. The SDWA mandates that EPA publish MCLGs and promulgate national primary drinking water regulations (NPDWR) for 83 specific contaminants prior to June, 1989. The inorganic contaminants evaluated in this document are included on this list. Since the proposed standards and monitoring requirements for lOCs have been mandated by statute, EPA is limited in its consid- eration of alternative regulatory approaches and strategies for implementation of the SDWA. EPA does not have the flexibility to consider taking “no action,” nor can the Agency propose that states establish the necessary standards and monitoring requirements based on Federal guidance. Under these constraints, the Agency is committed to setting explicit MCLs for each contaminant as close to the MCLG “as is feasible,” or in the absence of feasible analytical methodology, a treatment requirement. 1.4 Assessment of Total Costs Estimates of aggregate national costs for proposed alternative MCLs for lOCs are based on individual results for each contaminant evaluated. Because nitrite levels in drinking water are considered to be negligible relative to nitrate levels, and due to nitrite’s tendency to be oxidized to nitrate during disinfection, it was assumed that incremental impacts of the nitrite regulation beyond those calculated for nitrate would be negligible and no further analyses were performed for this chemical. As indicated above, it was assumed that treatment and waste disposal costs for removal of asbestos would be subsumed by the corrosion control and surface water treatment rules. The basic algorithm utilized in obtaining estimates for total national treatment costs is relatively straightforward. For each system size category, for both ground and surface systems, the number of systems with contamination above the MCL alternative is estimated. The number of systems is then. merged with a decision matrix which predicts the relative likelihood that a system of a given size and source will choose various treatment technologies or other compliance options. These estimates are then multiplied 1—3 ------- by the appropriate engineering costs developed for each technology or option. Net incremental capital costs associated with treatment and waste disposal at the most stringent MCL alternatives in systems serving fewer than 50,000 persons are approximately $40.8 billion, excluding mercury. The incremental operation and maintenance (O&M) costs are approximately $4.5 billion per year, resulting in annu- alized costs of $7.3 billion using a three percent discount rate, $7.8 using five percent, and $8.4 billion using a seven percent discount rate over 20 years. These may be overestimates due to the potential for co-occurrence at these concentrations. Capital costs associated with the proposed MCL alternatives for systems serving less than 50,000 persons are approximately $73 million, with O&M costs of $6 million per year. This results in annualized treatment and waste disposal costs of $1]. million per year (Exhibit 1-1). Exhibit i-i Incremental Cost of IOC Rule at Proposed MCL Alternatives Capital Costs 0 & N ( Million 1986 $) IMillion 1986 S/Year ) Treatment 40 4 Waste Disposal 33 2 Monitoring 0 2 State Programs o 0 Total 73 8 Total Annualized Costs (@ 3% Over 20 years) $11 Million/Year (excluding monitoring costs) $13 Million/Year (including monitoring costs) The standard errors of the national costs of compliance were estimated for cadmium at an MCL of 5 ugh. The estimates of uncertainty apply to capital, O&M, and annualized costs, on the assumption that errors in capital and O&M costs are perfectly 1—4 ------- correlated. It also applies to the compliance cost (i.e., the cost of meeting the proposed MCL minus the cost of meeting the NIPDWR) . The errors in cost range from 20 to 28 percent of the mean value for cadmium. Monitoring cost estimates for each contaminant include ana- lytical costs averaged over an 1]. year period and were derived using the proposed monitoring requirements outlined in the draft Phase II proposal. Models were developed for calculating high and low bound estimates for total annual monitoring costs for each contaminant. The estimated total cost of monitoring for inorganic con- taminants under the interim regulations is reported in the Public Water System Supervision Program (PWSSP) Information Collection Request (ICR) as $3.3 million. It is estimated that $2.0 million of the interim regulation’s costs would be incurred due to moni- toring for the sub-set of contaminants evaluated in this analysis. Incremental monitoring costs for lOCs can be estimated by subtracting the costs associated with the interim regulations from those calculated for the proposed revised regulations. This results in average incremental monitoring costs of $2.1 million per year under the low bound scenario, and $3.3 million per year under the high bound at the proposed MCL alternatives. In addition to these annual monitoring costs, it is estimated that there will be a one-time cost to monitor the unregulated contaminants that ranges from $0.2 to $1.6 million. An estimate of the total costs to state programs for the entire Phase II regulatory package (i.e., including both lOCs and synthetic organic chemicals) is included in the draft Regulatory Impact Analysis for Synthetic Organic Chemiàals. 1.5 Assessment of Benefits Traditionally, benefits of removing contamination from drinking water are expressed in terms of cases of disease avoided. Since all lOCs are being regulated based on sub-lethal health effects, and no usable dose/response data were available for these contaminants, it was impossible to calculate the number of cases of adverse health effects avoided. For this reason, benefits associated with the regulation of lOCs in drinking water are presented only in terms of a reduction in the population exposed under the various MCL alternatives. The net incremental reduction in exposure derived through adoption of the most stringent MCL alternatives for each contam- inant is approximately 102 million persons in systems serving fewer than 50,000 persons. Excluding the systems estimated to have occurrence of mercury, a net reduction of approximately 99 million 1—5 ------- persons exposed is estimated. The estimated net incremental reduction in exposure derived through adoption of the proposed MCL alternatives for cadmium is approximately 170,000 persons in systems serving fewer than 50,000 persons. In addition to reduced exposure, the total annual baseline cancer cases due to asbestos exposure were calculated depending on assumptions used regarding population exposed and average concentration in affected systems. It is estimated that between 0.06 and 0.3 cases occur annually in community water systems. Note that the above estimates of health damages avoided represent an underestimate of the total benefits because certain intangible benefits are not included. Of particular importance is the value of an extra margin of safety -- a warranty -- which pro- vides assurance to consumers, and to society as a whole, that it can be taken for granted that the water is safe to drink. 1.6 Reqillatory Flexibility, and Paperwork Reduction Analyses Because of the health risks associated with inorganic contam- inants, the nature of their occurrence in public water supplies, and the generally limited treatment currently in place, the revised standards for these contaminants are likely to affect small surface water systems. EPA guidelines on compliance with the Regulatory Flexibility Act indicate that, in general, a “substantial” number of small entities is more than 20 percent of the total. Of the estimated 199,390 public water supplies serving fewer than 50,000 persons, 192 (0.1 percent) systems will incur incremental treatment and waste disposal costs as a result of the revised IOC regulations (assuming MCLs are set equivalent to the MCLGs for non-carcino- gens). Therefore, by the 20 percent rule, the proposed bC regulations would not affect a “substantial” number of small water utilities at the proposed MCL alternatives. Under the RFA, annual costs of compliance are to be compared to the existing cost of production. Agency guidance regarding the RFA defines a percentage increase in production cost of five percent or more as a significant impact. A macro-level, or aggregate, analysis produced an estimate of the percentage increase in production costs to range from 0.05 to 0.15. Alternatively, a micro-level analysis was conducted to examine the percentage increase in production cost for affected systems within a system size category. The micro—level analysis indicates the incremental production cost increase to range from 63 to 206 percent, with an average increase of 146 percent in systems serving less than 50,000 persons. A detailed discussion of the number of water systems affected by monitoring and paperwork requirements associated with the 1—6 ------- proposed rules is provided in the Information Collection Request Document. 1.7 Summary of Costs and Benefits The “best estimates” of total national incremental impacts of the proposed ICC regulations are summarized in Exhibit 1-2. As described above the standard error for incremental treatment and waste disposal costs at the proposed MCL alternatives is between 20 and 28 percent of the values presented, depending on the assumption used regarding the correlation of errors across contaminants. 1—7 ------- EXHIBIT 1-2 Incremental Impacts of Proposed IOC Regulations At Proposed MCL Alternatives No. Systems Affected : 192 Compliance Costs : Treatment/Waste Disposal — Total Capital 73 (Million 1986 5) Treatment/Waste Disposal - 0 & M 6 (Million 1986 $/Year) Total Annualized @ 3% Over 20 Years 11 (Million 1986 S/Year) Monitoring (Million 1986 S/Year) 2 State Programs (Million 1986 5/Year) 01 Total Annual Costs (Million 1986 $/Year) 13 (Million 1986 S/Year) Average Increased Household Costs (1986 5/Year) 2 System Size (Pop. Served) Best Estimate Range 25—500 461 286—571 501—3300 126 97—151 3301—50,000 72 52—78 > 50,000 0 N/A Benefits : Reduction in Population Exposed 170,000 Persons 1 lncluded with estimates for proposed Synthetic Organic Chemicals regulations. 2 Average increased household costs are only for systems affected by the rule. 1—8 ------- 2. PROBLEM DEFINITION 2.1 Introduction Potential threats to public health due to contamination of drinking water supplies with inorganic chemicals (IOCs) have long been recognized. Along with microbiological contaminants, lOCs were among the first substances to be regulated under the Public Health Service Act of 1962 and the original Safe Drinking Water Act (SDWA) of 1974. The regulatory initiatives evaluated in this document involve the revision of existing standards and estab- lishinent o new standards for eight IOCs determined to be of sig- nificance. Exhibit 2—1 summarizes the available health effects inform- ation on the lOCs addressed in this document. Also included in Exhibit 2-1 is a summary of the proposed Maximum Contaminant Level Goals (MCLGs) for each contaminant. Under the SDWA, EPA must set MCLGs “...at the level at which no known or anticipated adverse effects on the hea th of persons occur and which allows an adequate margin of safety.” MCLGS are unenforceable goals which serve as the basis for setting the enforceable Maximum Contaminant Levels (MCL5). For substances that have exhibited strong evidence of car- cinogenicity the Agency’s policy is that MCLGs are set at zero. For substances exhibiting “equivocal” evidence of carcinogenicity, MCLGs are set based on sub-lethal health effects plus an additional uncertainty factor. For substances with inadequate or no evidence of carcinogenicity, MCLGs are set based solely upon sub-lethal health effects. Complicating the task of determining “safe” levels of exposure to lOCs in drinking water is the fact that some of these substances have been shown to be essential for proper human nutrition as trace elements. The Agency has developed long-term drinking water equivalent levels (DWELs) which serve as the basis for determining thq MCLGs for lOCs via the procedure described below. For non-carcinogens, threshold levels at which no adverse, sub-lethal health effects are anticipated to occur for chronic periods of exposure are determined from human or animal studies. This threshold is referred to as either the no observed adverse effect level (NOAEL) or lowest observed adverse effect level 1 1n addition to the lOCs evaluated in this document, revised standards will be proposed for arsenic, lead and copper. Impacts of these regulation will be evaluated in separate documents. 2 SDWA Section 1412 (b) (4) 2—1 ------- EXHIBIT 2—1 SUNMAFY OF HEALTH EFFECTS FOR I NOFGANIC CHE I IICAIS • I I I I I I I I • I I Peripheral yes- : Selenoals • gas- cular collapse. : trvintestinal SE Ifl IILRI lesions of heart.: distress, liver I kidney and spleen and spines Pu1ncna edema effects CHILD ADULT I I 1—DAY H A (UG/L) 1: io-n&y H A (W/L) EWEL PROPCGED ESSENTIAL NITFRIBIT CARC1NCX3E I’IICI lY (W/L) MCER : : /L V/ l i , RDI2(w/DAY): CLASS :7mill ion: : : :7mil lion N/A : N/A : H/A : N/A : N/A :fibez-s/1: N : ti/A : A 6 : fibers/i : 1ouin: : : : (>lOum) I I I ‘ I I I — I — — I I I I I • • I I I I • • ti/A : N/A: N/A I N/A :5.000:5.000: ti: N/A : D : N/A I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I ti/A : N/A 1,400:5 ,000 1 200 100 : Y : 50—200 : A 5 : N/A (CrVI) : (CrVI) : (CrVI) : 1(CrUflI 1 (CrVIfl I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I N/A fl/A N/A ,ID N/A 10,000 : iii,ooo 1 10,000 : xo,ooo 6 : : (1000) (11,000) : (1000) 1 (100t H : N I N/A D N/A I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I 1 I $ • I I I • I I I I I I I • I • I I I I U I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I 41 1 144 : 106 5 0 : Y : 50—200 : D : N/A I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I 1 H A - Health Advisory 2 RDI - Recongnended daily intake 3 N/A - information not available - 4 Via inhalation exjcsure Regulated for drinking water pirposea as if it were in Group C 5 Regulated for drinking water gurposes as if it were in Group D 6 In addition, PICLG for total nitrate and nitrite z 10 mg/i (as N) INOEGANIC HEALTH EFFECFS OVTA MNA I IF GifiONIC I Possible cancer ASI3ESTC$ N/A I of the stomach and pancreas Gastrointestinal I Hypertension, BARIUH : distress, hyper- Cardiovascular tension, neuro- effects suscular effects Gastrointestinal : Kidney and liver CAEt IILI 1 I distress, liver : damage, anemia, & kidney failure,: hypertension, renal dysfunction: &ne damage CHRct lllfl l Liver and kidney damage, intermal bleeding, nausea, vomiting Respiratory dis- orders, derma- titis, ulceration of the skin Gastrointestinal : Kidney damage, MERCURY Distress, kidney I Central nervous : N/A : N/A failure system effects I I I I__ — — , Methescglobin- NITRATE : enia, Neurceuscu-: Central nervous (NITRITE) lar effects, kid- system effects : N/A : N/A ney damage, car— diotoxicity N/A N/A ------- (LOAEL). Depending on the nature of the toxicological data avai- lable for a given substance, an uncertainty factor between one and 1,000 j s applied to the NOAEL or I OAEL to compute a Reference Dose (RfD).’ The DWEL 4 is then calculated by converting the RfD into a drinking water concentration. The DWEL calculation assumes that total exposure is through drinking water for an average person of 70 kg body weight consuming two liters of water per day. The DWELs for the lOCs are presented in Exhibit 2-1. Finally, to determine the MCLG, the relative contribution to total exposure from other sources is taken into account. Because lOCs have been comparatively well—studied, sufficient data are generally available on the contribution from food and air. For these contaminants, the MCLG was generally calculated by account- ing for the contribution from food and the contribution from air reflected in the DWEL. The above calculations can be summarized as follows: NOAEL (or LOAEL) RfD (in mg/kg/day) Uncertainty Factor(s) RfD x Body Weight (70 kg for adults ) DWEL (in mg/i) = Drinking Water Consumption (2 1/day) Percent of total exposure from MCLG (in mg/i) = DWEL * Drinking Water In cases where relative source contribution data are suff i- cient, the DWEL is multiplied by the actual percentage of total exposure accounted for by drinking water, if actual drinking water exposure is determined to be between 20 and 80 percent of the total. If the data show that actual exposure is lest than 20 percent from drinking water, 20 percent will be used as a minimum. In cases where drinking water accounts for more than 80 percent of the total exposure, 80 percent will be used as a maximum. Where data are insufficient, contribution from drinking water to total exposure is assumed to be approximately 20 percent. More detailed descriptions of the derivation of the one and 10-Day Health Advisories, RfD, DWELs, and MCLGs can be found in the Health Criteria Documents prepared for each contaminant, and in the draft Federal Register proposal. The remainder of this chapter outlines additional background information on bc contamination in drinking water. The following 3 me reference dose was formerly referred to as the Acceptable Daily Intake or ADI. 4 me DWEL was formerly referred to as the adjusted acceptable daily intake level or kADI. 2—3 ------- sections summarize four major topics: health effects; occurrence; treatment technologies; and analytical detection methods. Further summary information on each contaminant is presented in the Fact Sheets in Appendix I. Readers are directed to the EPA-ODW publications cited for each of these topics for more thorough and detailed discussions. 2.2 Health Effects 5 Available evidence suggests that adverse health effects attributable to bc exposure involve acute or chronic sub-lethal endpoints of toxicity. As discussed above, the threshold concen- trations at which no sub-lethal health effects are anticipated to occur generally form the basis for MCLGs. However, three contami- nants evaluated under this proposal have also exhibited evidence of carcinogenicity; these are cadmium, chromium, and asbestos. The strength of evidence of carcinogenicity via drinking water exposure for these substances is described below. While cadmium and cadmium compounds have been shown to induce tumors at several sites through injection and inhalation exposure in animal studies, no evidence has been found linking cadmium ingestion with carcinogenicity in animals or humans. EPA has classified cadmium in Group Bi according to the Proposed Guidelines for Carcinogen Risk Assessment. However, since there are inade- quate data to characterize the presence or lack of carcinogenic hazard through ingestion exposure, cadmium will be regulated as though it was classified in Group D. Chromium (CrVI) compounds were shown to be carcinogenic in animals via injection exposure. In addition, epidemiological studies have demonstrated a link between prolonged inhalation of Chromium VI compounds and the incidence of lung and respiratory tract cancers. Based on this evidence, chromium is classified in Group A, according to EPA’s Proposed Guidelines for Carcinogen Risk Assessment. However, since there are inadequate data to charac- terize the presence or lack of a carcinogenic hazard from ingestion exposure, chromium will be regulated as though it was classified in Group D. Although inhalation exposure to asbestos has been shown to produce a high incidence of lung tumors and inesothelioma in lab- oratory animals, the majority of studies involving ingestion exposure have failed to produce carcinogenic effects. In 1984 however, the National Toxicology Program (NTP) reported that “some evidence of carcinogenicity” was observed in one sex of one species 5 Sources of information contained in this section are gener- ally, 50 Federal Register 46957—46975, November 13, 1985, and the Health Effects chapters of the Criteria Documents for lOCs. 2—4 ------- exposed to intermediate range (i.e., greater than 10 urn in length) chrysotile asbestos fibers via ingestion. 6 In this study, a significant increase was observed in the number of epithelial neo- plasms in the digestive tracts of male F344/N rats. In addition, there have been several epidemiological studies which have shown gastrointestinal cancer to be associated with occupational exposure to asbestos. The question of whether this observed increased risk of gastrointestinal cancer is due to ingestion of inhaled fibers has not been fully resolved, however. Asbestos has been classified as a Group A carcinogen accord- ing to EPA’S Proposed Guidelines for Carcinogen Assessment, based on evidence of human carcinogenicity via inhalation exposure. Because of the limited evidence of carcinogenicity via ingestion, EPA is proposing to regulate asbestos as if it were in Group C for drinking water purposes. Based on the evidence in the NTP report described above and the use of the “one-hit” model, EPA has calculated estimates for ingestion of asbestos via drinking water. The concentration w ich corresponds to a lifetime individual excess cancer risk of l0 is approximately 7 million intermediate range fibers per liter (MFL). This level is also being proposed by the Agency as the MCLG. 2.3 Occurrence For each contaminant, the basis for all calculations of impacts is the estimated number of public water systems (and in turn, the number of persons) affected above a given concentration. Occurrence estimates for all lOCs except asbestos were based on one or more of five national surveys. For groundwater systems, the National Inorganic and Radionuclides Survey (NIRS) provided the primary source of occurrence data for all contaminants except nitrate. For surface water systems, no single comprehensive national survey has been conducted for lOCs. Consequently, the results of four surveys were pooled to provide adequate baseline data. These surveys are the Community Water Supply Study (1969), the Community Water Supply Survey (1978), the Rural Water Survey (RWS), and the National Organics Monitoring Survey (NOMS). The NIRS sampling protocol ensured that samples represented water in the distribution systems and specified flushing for at least three minutes to avoid the influence of corrosion products, including cadmium. Review and analysis of the occurrence data was performed for EPA Office of Drinking Water by Science Applications International Corporation (SAIC). Based on that review, SAIC developed statisti- 650 Federal Register No. 219, pg. 46962. 2—5 ------- cal distributions of the occurrence probabilities at various concentrations for each contaminant. These probablities were formulated by system size category and water source. A “delta” log—normal distribution used to represent the national occurrence distribution and forms the basis for subsequent calculations. This methodology assumes that all positive sampling results are log- normally distributed and was considered most appropriate since it corresponds well with the actual survey data. Under this inethodol- ogy, nothing is assumed about the distribution of concentrations in results below the minimum reporting levels. The delta log- normal model is illustrated in Exhibit 2-2 below. At the time the occurrence analysis was conducted, all NIRS data were not available. Estimates for groundwater systems are therefore based on approximately 85 percent of the NIRS data. Recent comparison of occurrence probabilities derived through analysis of 100 percent of the data with those originally used in the draft RIA show a maximum variation of 1.5 percent for all contaminants. On this basis, it was assumed that the use of updated occurrence data would result in insignificant changes and would be well within the bounds of uncertainty. For this reason, not because of the schedule constraints involved, impacts were not recalculated using the updated set of occurrence data. In arriving at estimates of systems affected/population exposed, the following methodology was employed. A model (referred to as “Replicate”) was developed to replicate the delta log-normal distribution results on Lotus spreadsheets. This model utilizes statistical parameters calculated for each contaminant by source and system size category, and allows estimation of occurrence probabilities at MCL alternatives not explicitly considered in the draft occurrence documents. The model also facilitates estimation of the average concentration levels in affected systems. The results of the Replicate calculations for lOCs are presented in Appendix II. It should b noted however, that estimates at concentrations below the MQC for a contaminant are less reliable and subject to a greater degree of uncertainty. The most stringent MCL alternatives analyzed for barium, cadmium, mercury, and nitrate are subject to this qualification. 7 Science Applications International Corp., 1987. Preliminary National Drinking Water Occurrence and Exposure Estimates for Phase II Inorganjcs . 8 The MQC is the minimum level at which quantitative analyti- cal results are considered reliable for a given set of survey data. This is distinct concept from the practical quantification limit (PQL), and is explained in further detail in the draft occurrence documents for each bC. The MQCs and PQLs are not necessarily equivalent for these contaminants. 2—6 ------- EXHIBIT General Form of Delta Log—Normal .6 .5 .4 .3 .2 .1 0 Di tribution Minimum Reporting Level MRL) Co N CE NT RATIO N — Represents proportion of total 4amples < MRL for which it is not possible to describe a itistributi n (i.e.. this represents the delta portion of the overall listribution PROBABILITY of CC [ l:I I:N E 2 4 5 2—7 ------- To obtain estimates of actual number of systems affected and population exposed, results from the Replicate model are merged with the data on total numbers of systems and population served by source and system size presented in Exhibit 2-3. The standardized data in Exhibit 2-3 are based on a FRDS run conducted in March, 1986 and have been corroborated by data collected in Conjunction with a recent survey by the Association of State Drinking Water Administrators. It is recognized however, that these estimates may be subject to change due to inconsistencies in reporting procedures, and the fact that the number and status of public water systems (PWSs) nationwide are in a constant state of flux. To maintain consistency between the disparate data sets used in the calculation of impacts, it was necessary to rectify a discrepancy between the form in which the occurrence probabilities were originally displayed, and that required as an input to the ATm cost model. Although both data sets were arrayed in 12 system size categories by population served, the size categories did not match. Since the cost model size categories were matched to those used in the Cost and Technology Documents, it was considered most appro- priate to convert the occurrence data accordingly. As displayed in Exhibit 2-4 below, it was assumed that the same probabilities calculated using the original draft SAIC occurrence information would apply to system sizes that overlap. 9 Association of State Drinking Water Administrators, 1986. Survey to Support Analysis of Impacts of Proposed Regulations Concerning Filtration and Disinfection of Public Drinking Water Supplies . September 16 draft. 2—8 ------- EXHIBIT 2—3 Standardized Nt.iiters of Public Water Systems and Populations Served by Source and Size Categories I SizeCategory 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 I Pop. Served 25-100 101-500 501 1K 1K-3.3K 3.3K1OK 1OK-25K 25K-SOK 50K-75K 75K-lOOK 100K-SOOK 500K-is Over 114 Total Conmunity Water Systems SUFACE WATER SYSTEMS I Purchased Systems 620 1,343 741 1,197 613 308 166 63 29 38 3 2 5,123 Non Purchased Systems 833 779 754 1,040 1,156 569 328 157 108 175 43 15 5,957 Total Systems 1,453 2,122 1,495 2,237 1,769 877 494 220 137 213 46 17 11,080 Total Populations (000s) 90 570 1,280 4,330 10,200 12,640 15,910 10,310 10,090 36,770 22,380 30,090 154,660 I Non - Cosninity Water Systems I PurchasedSystems 6-44 177 49 30 13 0 3 0 0 0 0 0 9161 Non Purchased Systems 2,110 1,069 192 135 50 2 0 0 1 1 0 0 3,560 I Total Systems 2,754 1,246 241 165 63 2 3 0 1 1 0 0 4,476 I Total Populations (000s) 134 310 198 301 375 50 88 0 82 360 0 0 1,898 I Non Transient Non Coom. Systems I PurchasedSystems 91 25 7 4 2 0 3 0 0 0 0 0 1321 NonPurchasedSystems 298 151 27 19 7 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 5041 TotalSystems 389 176 34 23 9 0 3 0 1 1 0 0 636 1 Total Populations (000s) 19 44 28 42 53 7 88 0 82 360 0 0 723 Conmiunity Water Systems GROUND WAlER SYSTEMS I Purchased Systems 221 540 244 268 92 37 13 3 0 3 0 0 1,421 p Non Purchased Systems 17,079 15,354 5,038 5,185 2,308 823 278 77 17 39 4 0 46,202 I Total Systems 17,300 15,894 5,282 5,453 2,400 860 291 80 17 42 4 0 47,623 I Total Populations (000s) 950 3,850 3,910 10,000 13,310 13,110 9,540 4,710 1,360 7,600 2,760 0 71,160 Non - Coniunity Water Systems PurchasedSystems 385 60 9 5 2 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 4631 Non Purchased Systems 98,453 28,078 8,155 1,455 349 25 1 1 6 2 7 - 0 0 136,541 I Total Systems 98,838 28,138 8,164 1,460 351 27 11 6 2 7 0 0 137,004 Total Populations (000s) 4,355 6,637 7,193 2,485 1,934 503 275 398 180 1,096 0 0 25,056 Non Transient Non Corn. Systems I PurchasedSystems 54 8 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 65 1 Non Purchased Systems 13,899 3,964 1,151 205 49 4 11 6 2 7 0 0 19,298 Total Systems 13,953 3,972 1,153 206 50 4 11 6 2 7 0 0 19,364 I Total Populations (000s) 615 937 1 .015 351 273 71 275 398 180 1,096 0 0 5,211 I Total populations include those served by purchased and non-purchased water systems. Non purchased water systems conprise of systems treating their own source water supplies and exclude systems purchasing water from other sources. Totals may not tally due to independent rounding 11 12 oI ------- EXHIBIT 2—4 Conversion of Occurrence Data to Standardized System Size Categories (by Population Served) System Size 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Cateaorv Draft SAIC Occurrence Document 25—100 101—500 501—1000 1001—2500 2 5 01—3 3 00 3301—5000 5001—10,000 10, 001—25, 000 25,001—50,000 50, 001—75, 000 75,001—100,000 100, 000+ Standardized f or Draft RIA 2 5—100 101—500 501—1000 1001—33 00 3301—10,000 10, 001—25,000 25,001—50,000 50, 001—75, 000 75, 001—100, 000 100,001—500,000 500, 000—1, 000, 000 1,000,000+ The data 1 ° summarized in Exhibit 2-5 illustrate another potential source of error in calculating impacts for the proposed IOC rule. Comparison of the FRDS violation data with estimates of number of community systems affected at the interim MCLs calculated using the “Replicate” methodology described above i11ust tes that some error is inherent in one or both of the data sets, 1 - despite their agreement in the total number of systems affected for several contaminants. 10 FRDS violation data were compiled in the draft occurrence documents for each contaminant. 11 1t should be noted that the “number of systems affected” in Exhibit 2-4 does not correspond precisely to the “number of systems incurring treatment costs” (presented in Chapter 4 and in Appendix III) since both purchased and non-purchased water systems are included in the former calculation, and only non-purchased systems in the latter. 2—10 ------- EXHIBIT 2-5 Community Water Systems Contamination Greater or Equal to Current with bC Than MCLs IOC (current MCL in ug/l) FRDS Violations 12 RIA Estimate of Tot Systems Affected Ground Surface Water Water Total Ground Surface Water Water Total As noted above, it was necessary to combine several data sets to derive occurrence estimates for surface water systems. The quality and quantity of data in these surveys (especially the RWS) varied significantly. As a result, the accuracy of these estimates may be questionable. Although the majority of occurrence seems to be in groundwater systems, significant surface water occurrence is estimated for some contaminants. For example, mercury is estimated to have an average occurrence probability of 6.62 percent in surface water systems at a concentration greater than the proposed MCLG of 2 ugh. Intuitively, this seems extremely high and may not be an accurate representation of field conditions. This is supported by the analysis of FRDS violations data which indicate 12 Source: SAIC draft occurrence documents, data current as 13 Includes both purchased and non-purchased systems. Barium (1000) 73 1 74 Cadmium (10) 31 6 37 Chromium (50) 25 3 28 Mercury (2) 38 19 57 Nitrate (10,000) 726 75 801 Selenium (10) Total 208 17 225 848 1191 121 1222 Total less Mercury SW 1191 102 1203 848 14 0 48 0 6 26 34 733 767 669 22 691 929 196 1777 1044 of FY—1986. 2—il ------- that there were only 19 violations of the r teriin mercury MCL of 2.0 ugh in surface water systems in 1986 (see Exhibit 2-5) Exhibit 2-5 also illustrates inconsistencies for contaminants such as selenium where most occurrence estimated using the Replicate model is in surface systems whereas the FRDS violation data suggest the opposite. In addition to the uncertainty associated with the raw data used to estimate national occurrence, at least two other potential sources of error are inherent in the occurrence estimates. First, because of the methodology used to consolidate survey data, some small probability of occurrence is assigned to all system size categories, including the largest systems. Thus, while the model may project only a “fraction” of a system in the larger size categories to be affected, this may still result in an estimate of significant impacts due to the high unit costs and large populations served in these systems. Since more extensive and sophisticated monitoring and treatment practices are generally in place at systems serving greater than 50,000 persons, the likelihood of bC occurrence at levels of concern relative to that in smaller systems is probably negligible. Based on this ration- ale, it is assumed that occurrence of lOCs is negligible in the larger system size categories ‘for purposes of calculating incremen- tal impacts (see Chapters 4 and 5). Second, the phenomenon of co-occurrence was evaluated based the assumption of joint, independent probabilities of occurrence for individual contaminants. It was estimated that approximately one percent of affected systems have occurrence of two contaminants (see Exhibit 2-6). On this basis, it was assumed that a much smaller number of systems would have simultaneous occurrence of three or more contaminants. Based on these r-esults, it was assumed that the degree of co—occurrence of lOCs (and resulting effects on the aggregate national impacts) is negligible and no analyses beyond those presented in Exhibit 2-6 were conducted. Comprehensive national surveys on occurrence of asbestos in drinking water supplies have not been undertaken. However, it is known that asbestos fibers may contaminate water sources through natural erosion of mineral deposits and through anthropogenic sources such as industrial discharges and runoff from mine tail- ings. In addition, corrosion and tapping of asbestos/cement pipes may contaminate water in distribution systems, particularly in 14 Science Applications International Corporation, 1987. Estimated National Occurrence and Exposure to Mercury in Public Drinkin Water Supplies (Revised Draft) . Section 2.2. 2—12 ------- DRAFT EXHIBIT 2—6 Summary of Co—Occurrence in All Community Water Systems JUN 301991 - C ’ VT 0.03Z 0.04Z 0.4 5t 0.63X Contam i nant AFFECTED AFFECTED AF FEC TED TOTAL POPULATION TOTAL POPULATION POPULATION SURFACE SURFACE GROUND GROUND ALL ALL Proposed Co-cant- Preposed WATER WATER WATER WATER WATER WATER NCL am:nant MCL SYSTEMS SYSTEMS SYSTEMS SYSTEMS SYSTEMS SYSTEMS Arsenic 50 Barium 1500 0 0 0 0 0 0 Arsenic 50 Cadmium 5 0 0 0 43 0 43 Arsenic 50 Chromium 120 0 20 0 0 0 2 f l Arsenic 50 Capper [ 300 0 22 0 7 0 29 Arsenic 50 lead 20 0 42 143 186 Arsenic 50 Mercury 3 1 17,933 0 1 1 1798 ’ Arsenic 50 Nitrate 10 0 1,482 0 124 0 1606 Arsenic 50 Selenium 45 0 0 0 0 0 Barium 1500 Cadmium 5 0 0 0 4 0 4 Barium 1500 Chromium 120 0 0 0 0 0 ?arium 15fl0 Copper 13 f l0 0 0 0 1 : Eariu:i 1500 Lead 20 0 0 12 ‘ C ar:um 1500 Mercury 3 I l i i u i l Barin 1500 Nitrate kO 0 0 0 i .1 ?ariuu 130O Selenium 15 0 0 ‘ 1 “ Cadmium 5 Chromium 120 0 0 0 1 0 1 Cadmium 5 Copper l3 l 0 9 0 0 414 0 l4 Cadm ium 5 Lead 20 0 0 5 7,997 5 1.997 Cadmium 5 Mercury 3 0 0 41 0 47 Cadmium 5 Nitrate 10 0 0 4 6911 4 E91 1 Cadmium 5 Selenium 45 0 0 ii 0 0 , Chromium 120 Copper 1300 0 1 0 0 0 1 Chromium 120 Lead 20 Q I A 4 5 Chromium 120 Mercury 3 0 411 0 0 0 ‘71 Chromium 120 Nitrate 10 0 39 1 3 0 42 Chromium 120 Selenium 45 fl 0 0 0 0 0 Copper 1300 Lead 20 0 1 1 1,372 1 LP’ Copper 1300 Mercury 3 fl 506 0 9 0 511 Copper 1300 Nitrate 10 0 42 1 1 ,196 I 1,223 Copper k300 Seleniun 45 0 0 0 0 ‘ ‘ Lead 20 Mercury 3 1 9 93 :56 , 0 Lead 20 Nitrate 10 0 81 13 22,921 13 :, ) 2 Lead 20 Selenium £5 0 0 0 0 0 0 Mercur 3 Nitrate 10 1 34,462 t) ITS 1 34.5 Mercury 3 Selenium 45 1 0 A i l 0 Nitrate 10 Selenium 45 U ) 0 ‘) 0 Total Co—occurrence Percent of all systems Percent of Total Occurrence 25 41,501 0. 06Z 39 .i5 t tl• 4X 1.29t i.37t 1.’)7t 0 .927. ------- areas with highly aggressive natural waters. 15 Depending on the location and other specific characteristics of the water system, the size, type, and concentration of asbestos fibers may be highly variable. Based on a compilation of several studies of limited geo- graphic scope, EPA estimates that as many as 3,234 public water systems nationwide may have occurrence of asbestos fibers greater than 10 urn in length in concentrations exceeding 0.071 MFL. of these systems, t least 609 may have levels which exceed the proposed MCLG. 1 This occurrence is generally restricted to systems with some asbestos/cement pipe in their distribution systems, or in surface water systems in regions of the country having significant asbestos-containing mineral deposits (i.e., California and Washington state). Twenty-six (4.3%) of the systems estimated to have occurrence in excess of the proposed MCLG are surface water systems without asbestos/cement pipe. 2.4 Treatment Technologies The most appropriate centralized treatment technologies for removal of lOCs from drinking water are varied and generally depend on a number of physical and chemical parameters of the contaminants and source waters. In general, metals which form insoluble precipitates lend themselves to removal by conventional filtration processes or lime softening. Metals which complex in aqueous solutions will require more technologically intensive processes. Non-metals (e.g., nitrate and nitrite) generally do not form salts with low enough solubilities for removal by conventional processes and therefore may also require more advanced types of treatments such as ion exchange. However, because it is readily oxidized to nitrate, any instances of nitrite contamination of source water would generally be rectified through disinfection of the water supply prior to distribution. Applicable technologies for IOC removal are summarized below. Detailed descriptions of bC treatment technologies are provided l5 EPA, Office of Drinking Water, Criteria and Standards Division, 1987. Drinking Water Criteria Document for Asbestos ( revised Draft) . PP. IV-2 — IV—3. 16 Ibid., pg. IV-12. It should be noted that at the time the asbestos occurrence analysis was conducted, an MCLG and proposed MCL of 7.1 MFL was assumed and therefore may represent a slight underestimate of the number of systems with occurrence above the current proposed MCL of 7 MFL. 2—14 ------- in the appropriate draft “Cost ar Technology Documents” published by the Office of Drinking Water. Conventional Treatment Processes This process is generally used for removal of color or tur- bidity from surface waters. The water treatment process usually involves the following steps: mixing with coagulants, floccula- tion, sedimentation, filtration, and disinfection. Removal of inorganics occurs through adsorption to or enmeshment in the floc. This process is generally effective for removal of cationjc inorganics (see Exhibit 2-7). For nitrate and barium however, the process is virtually ineffective. Lime Softening This process has traditionally been used to remove hardness from ground and surface waters. The process consists of the fol- lowing steps: softening with lime or soda ash, sedimentation, filtration, and disinfection. Like conventional treatment, inor- ganics removal occurs through adsorption on or enmeshment in the floc. In general the process is effective on cations but not on chromium VI, mercury, selenium, or nitrate (see Exhibit 2-8). EXHIBIT 2—7 lOCs for Which Conventional Treatment is Effective (Greater than 70 Percent Removal) With Alum Coaqulatjon With Iron Coaqu1atior Asbestos Asbestos Cadmium (at pH > 8.5) Cadmium (at pH > 8.0) Chromium III Chromium III Chromium VI (with ferrous salts) Mercury Selenium IV ‘ 7 u.s. Environmental Protection Agency - Office of Drinking Water, Criteria and Standards Division. 1986. Technologies and Costs for Removal of Inorganic Chemical Contaminants from Public Drinking Water Supplies . Draft documents prepared for each contaminant. 2—15 ------- EXHIBIT 2—8 lOCs for Which Lime Softening is Effective (Greater than 90 Percent Removal) Treatment Barium (at pH 9.5 - 10.8) Cadmium Chromium III (at pH > 10.5) Ion Exchange This process is used to remove hardness arid nitrates from groundwaters. Removal of inorganics occurs through adsorption to exchange sites on the resin. Typical unit processes include prefiltration (the process is effective only with extremely low turbidity waters), ion exchange, and disinfection. With the use of cationic resins, the process is effective on cationic morgan- ics, while the use of anionic resins is effective for nitrate and selenium (see Exhibit 2-9). EXHIBIT 2-9 lOCs for Which Ion Exchange Treatment is Effective (Greater than 90 Percent Removal) Anion Exchange Cation Exchange Chromium VI Barium Nitrate Cadmium Chromium Reverse Osmosis This process has traditionally been used in the desalination of seawater and brackish groundwaters. It involves forcing water through a filter membrane under pressure. Inorganics are removed by retention in the brine by the membrane. The process generally involves the following steps: pretreatment, membrane contact, and disinfection. This process is effective in treating for all lOCs at greater than 70 percent removal. 2—16 ------- Activated Alumina This process is used to remove inorganics from groundwaters through adsorption on the activated alumina. The process consists of the following steps: pretreatment, activated alumina contact, and disinfection. The process is effective in removing selenium IV and VI, but it is not effective in removing most cations. Activated Carbon Activated carbon (granular or powdered) is generally used for the removal of tastes, odors, and organic chemicals from surface waters. Inorganic chemical removal takes place through adsorption to the activated carbon. Typically, activated carbon use occurs as a unit process of conventional or lime softening treatment. Bone char activated carbon is effective in removing arsenic while granular or powdered activated carbon is effective on organic mercury. Other Alternatives Several alternatives to centralized treatment, including regionalization, welifield management, and alternate source, are available. For very small systems, exemptions to the requirements based on economic considerations may be available. Specific alternatives to centralized treatment are discussed below. Regionalization involves interconnection of one water system to an existing, adjacent system with excess capacity and acceptable quality. The affected community then usually purchases sufficient water to meet its needs. This technique i most frequently used by small water systems. Welifield management consists of pumping to waste from contam- inated wells, and increasing production from remaining wells. This technique is feasible only for systems that have enough remaining capacity to supply needs without drilling new wells (e.g., large groundwater systems). Alternate source involves developing a new water source and installing pipeline to replace a contaminated ground or surface water system. In general, this alternative is feasible only for small systems which have the option of drilling a new well and utilizing a groundwater source for which no treatment beyond that already in place is required. 2—17 ------- 2.5 Analytical Methods. 18 The Agency has proposed that analytical methods are available for all lOCs for which MCLGs have been proposed. A number of generally available detection methods exist such as furnace atomic absorption (AA), flame atomic absorption, and inductively coupled plasma (ICP) atomic emission spectrometry techniques. Exhibit 2- 10 lists proposed analytical methodologies for the lOCs, and practical quatitation limits (PQLs). Because impacts of the monitoring requirements for arsenic, lead, and copper are not addressed in this document, the analytical techniques for these substances are not included in this summary. This information will be included in separate ODW reports. For most lOCs use an AA technique or ICP are the accepted methods of detection. Two exceptions are mercury and nitrate. Analytical methods for mercury in drinking water include the manual and the automated cold vapor techniques. Nitrate detection is accomplished through calorimetric brucine, spectrometric cadmium reduction, and automated hydrazine and cadmium reductionteci -iniques. More details regarding analytical methodologies are provided in the Federal Register Volume 50, November 1985. 18 Federal Register 46957—46959. November 13, 1985. 2—18 ------- EXHIBIT 2—10 ANALYTICMJ METHODS FOR IOCS Inorganic Contaminants Detection I Practical I EPA Method and Methods : Limit (ugh) I Quantitation I Number Level (ugh) I U I I I I I I Asbestos ‘ N/A 1 1 I I Transmission Electron Microscopy 0.01 NFL I EPA I I I U U I 150 • Barium AA Flame 1 100 1 206.1 AA Furnace ‘ 2 I 208.2 • I I ICP • 2 ‘ S 200.7 I U I I I U I ‘Cadmium ‘ U 21 I U AA Furnace 1 0.1 1 213.2 IC? 1 1 I 200.7 U I I I U U I Chromium ‘ ‘ 10 1 * I AA Furnace 1 1 1 1 218.2 IC? 7 U 200.7 I I U I I I S * I ‘Mercury ‘ ‘ 05’ $ U . I U Manual Cold Yapor Technique U 0 2 ‘ 245.1 • • I 02 1 245.2’ Automated Cold Vapor Technique U U I I S I U U Nitrate 1 400 ‘ I U • Ion Chromatography U 10 ‘ 300.0 I I $ Automated Hydrazine Reduction I 10 ‘ I 353.1 U I - I Automated Cadmium Reduction 1 50 ‘ ‘ 353.2 1 U I Manual Cadmium Reduction U 10 ‘ U 353.3 I I S Ion Selective Electrode 1 1000 1 U U U I • U I I Nitrite 400 Spectrophotometric U 10 ‘ I 354.1 U I U • Automated Cadmium Reduction 50 I 353.2 Manual Cadmium Reduction 10 ‘ 1 353 3 • I Ion Chromatography • 4 ‘ U 300.0 I U U I U I U U I I • Selenium I U 10 ‘ • U I U AA; Gaseous Hydride I 2 ‘ ‘ 270.3 I I I AA Furnace ‘ 2 I 270.2 1 I I I icP 1 10 1 1 200.7 ------- 3. MARKET IMPERFECTIONS, THE NEED FOR FEDERAL REGULATION, AND CONSIDERATION OF REGULATORY ALTERNATIVES 3.1 Introduction The “Public” Nature of Water Supply Public water supply is an example of a “natural monopoly;” it would not be efficient to have multiple suppliers competing to build, operate, and maintain multiple systems of pipelines, res- ervoirs, wells and other facilities. Instead, a single entity performs these functions under public control. W1iile not a pure “public good” in the economic sense, drinking water is nonetheless a “publicly provided good” in that there is a significant government role in the pricing and production decisions of the industry. “Public” water supplies are typically either publicly owned and operated as a routine function of local government, or privately owned and publicly regulated as a routine function of state government. The concept of a “production function” is used to specify combinations of inputs to a production process which can be employed to produce alternative combinations of outputs. In competitive markets, producers attempt to find the optimal combinations of inputs and outputs to suit prevailing market conditions. Thus, the physical options in production are fixed by technical factors, but the choice between them is market driven. A natural monopoly such as water supply is an example of “market failure;” the competitive forces that would normally shape production decisions “fail” to perform. Therefore, the production function or publicly provided goods (i.e., the “social production function” ) embodies not only physical relationships between input and output combinations, but also a method for choosing among them. There are two essential questions that must be answered in orde to make optimal production decisions for publicly provided goods: o What price should be charged to ensure optimal utilization of any given level of service? o What is the optimal level of service to provide? 1 Schultze, C.L., The Politics And Economics of Public Spending , 1968, The Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C., ninth printing, 1977, p.56. 2 Layard and Walters, Microecorioniic Theory , 1978, McGraw Hill, New York, NY, p.171 and p.196. 3—1 ------- To maximize efficiency, prices would be set equal to marginal cost and decisions regarding the level of ervice would be based on comparisons of benefits and costs. In other words, institutions responsible for publicly provided goods should strive to mimic the processes of competitive markets. In competitive markets, these two questions are answered simultaneously and continuously through the presence of multiple suppliers. This is a successful way of operating because, across a range of price levels, consumer preferences for different levels of service are revealed in the transactions taking place in the market. There are two essential differences in the case of publicly provided goods. First, differential preferences regard- ing the level of service are not fully revealed in the face of a single monopoly price. Second, depending on the institutional arrangements in place, there may or may not be a direct relation- ship between the price charged and the level of service provided. 3.2 The Nature of the Imperfections Imperfect revelation of consumer preferences and flawed pricing policy are the two fundamental imperfections affecting the provision of public water supplies. The effects of these imperfections are manifest in the history of “underpricing” that characterizes the water industry. Water has been underpriced in one sense because the relative abundance and purity of available sources have long been taken for granted and not reflected in the price signal or the demand response. In another sense, water has been underpriced because the historical cost of water was so low that pricing practices evolved in ways unrelated to the cost of service in many places. The effect of these two concepts of underpricing are evident in the historical trend of water utility bills. The top panel of Exhibit 3-1 presents a comparison of annual family utility bills over the period from 1952 to l984. The bottom panel presents the same comparison in terms of the percentage of median family income. It is clear from these diagrams that rates for other utilities have grown at a much faster pace than those for sewer and water. In fact, it has been confirmed that the real price of water supply has 3 lbid, p. 174 4 BLS data. 3—2 ------- EXHIBIT 3—1 Percent of Median Family Income Spent on Selected Utilities 1952—1984 Annual for Selected Electric Phone — — Natural Gas Water (and Sewer) 1980 1990 Family Bills Utilities 1952—1984 $717 / 608 1 500— ‘ I 497 , / 400— ,/ ( ‘-I , 00—. I, ‘ / / 200H$18& . . / I / I - ___ 1950 1960 1970 Year 6 _ i 5. 4Z __________________________ I * S 3 J 2.ZX .65X .54X 1950 1960 1970 Year 3—3 Electric Phone — — - Natural Gas Water (and Sewer) 0 (J — 8 C a V 0 V U I. V 0 1980 1990 ------- actually declined over time. 5 ’ 6 Flaws In The Revelation of Consumer Preferences Centrally supplied potable water is a “multi-attribute good” which also has multiple uses. There are two major classes of attributes: quantity features and quality features. These may also be referred to as “pressure” and “purity.” Keeping pressure in the pipes is achieved by maintaining ade- quate flows and reliable performance throughout the water system - — from the water source(s) through treatment, storage, and distribution. In addition to the economic benefits of having a central water supply for a multitude of residential, commercial, and industrial uses, adequate capacity and pressure also serve a public safety purpose in providing fire fighting capability. Overlaid on these use-specific attributes is the more general attribute of reliability. As in all categories of infrastructure, there is an implied warranty that the system will not fail. Reliability of water service is taken for granted to the extent that the public reaches for the tap with the same confidence exhi- bited in flipping a light switch. The purity of the water delivered to water system customers is assured by performance of the treatment facilities. The purity attribute has four important elements: 1) aesthetic appeal (i.e., taste, odor, and appearance); 2) safety from acute health risks; 3) safety from chronic health risks; and, 4) public confidence that the water is safe to drink. This last attribute constitutes another implied warranty. Similar to other categories of infrastructure that affect public safety, the safety of potable water is largely taken for granted. For the most part, people fill a coffee pot with the same nonchalance they exhibit in driving across a bridge or stepping onto the elevator of an office building. To ensure provision of optimal levels of each of the multiple attributes of public water supply, each must be given appropriate weight in the production decisions by local water systems. Despite the fact most consumers have taken all of these attributes for granted for many years, the weights assigned in local decision- making processes have not always been optimal. The performance of 5 Mann, P.C., and LeFrancois, P.R., “The Real Price of Urban Water,” Journal of the American Water Works Association , January 1982, Vol. 74, No. 1. 6 Beattie, B.R. and Foster, H.S., “Can Prices Tame The Inflationary Tiger?” Journal of the American Water Works Associ- ation , August 1980, Vol 72, No. 8. 3—4 ------- water systems is commonly regarded as adequate as long as uninterupted delivery of the most readily noticeable attributes (e.g., pressure, aesthetic appeal, and protection from acute health risks) is maintained. Thus, these most “visible” attributes are accorded the greatest weight in decisionmaking. Problems involving planning for long term needs (e.g., infrastructure maintenance and replacement, chronic health risks) or low probability events (e.g., drought, waterborne disease outbreaks) tend to be underweighed in the local “public choice” environment. Flaws in Pricing and Capacity Planning Provision of water supply has historically been regarded as a “service delivery function.” Recently however, it has been acknowledged that an era of relative scarcity may be beginning which will force recognition of water as a “commodity.” It is generally agreed that, although the United States is not actually “running out of water,” it is “approaching the limits of inexpen- sive water.” 7 Within this context, water supply is both a service and a commodity; both characteristics are present in the quantity and quality attributes of the good. As alluded to above, a service orientation of “meeting capacity requirements” has traditionally predominated in local decisionmaking processes. Another facet of the service orientation is the belief that water supply should be provided at an affordable price as a publc service and, if necessary, supported by subsidy. To adjust to conditions of relative scarcity, however, a commodity orientation towards pricing and cap city planning must also be incorporated in local decisioninaking. In the future, there is likely to be a convergence of the factors which have historically been underweighted in local decisionmaking. Increased relative scarcity will make the untreat- ed source water (the basic commodity) more expensive. Treatment requirements imposed by the Safe Drinking Water Act Amendments of 1986 (SDWA) will increase the cost of producing “finished” water at the treatment plant. Deteriorating infrastructure, exemplified by leakage in the distribution system, will increase the cost of “delivered” water either through continued leakage of increasingly 7 Frederick, K., “The Legacy of Cheap Water,” Resources , Resources for the Future, Inc., spring, 1986. 8 For example: Lamm, Richard D., “Kicking The Cheap Water Habit: A New Era In Water Management,” in Water Values and Markets: Emerging Management Tools , The Freshwater Foundation, Navarre, Minnesota, 1986. :3—5 ------- valuable treated water or through the cost of making overdue repairs. Underpricing always implies excess capacity. The excess capacity in water supply may result in increased costs of compliance with regulations for water systems. One result of drinking water regulation, therefore, will be a reduction in the extent of this over capacity. Numerous water systems have already initiated more aggressive capacity management procedures in an attempt to meet demand more efficiently while, minimizing system loss. These measures are intended to reduce their anticipated costs of compliance with drinking water regulations. The economic efficiency of this adjustment cannot be precisely quantif led, but the net effect should be enhanced attention to resource allocation principles in the decisionmaking process. As a result, the overall change in society’s welfare would be positive. This is relevant to the evaluation of econmonic impacts of drinking water regulations because costs of compliance are currently calculated based on existing notions of capacity. It is likely that significant increases in consumers’ monthly water bills will result as the above noted convergence of factors affecting capacity costs occurs. The water supply industry has stressed the need to educate the public regarding the true value of potable water in order to mitigate adverse reactions to such increases. Given the market imperfections that exist, such public education would seem to be an efficient intervention. Since the historically low price levels of drinking water supplies may distort the response of consumers to corrective changes in prices, it is not clear that this response implies anything about the con- sumer’s true willingness to pay. When price signals are distort- ed, the demand response cannot be literally interpreted. 3.3 The Need for Federal Regulation The “market failure” induced by conditions of natural monopoly is not a failure of the mechanism of “private choice” to reveal preferences through consumer responses to prices. The under- weighting of certain attributes of public water supply in local decisionmaking processes reflects a failure of the “social pro- duction function” -- a failure of “public choice.” This failure cannot be fully corrected at the state or local level and is evident in both publicly owned and privately owned water systems as discussed below. Publicly Owned Water Systems Many publicly owned water systems exist in institutional settings in which water system revenues and costs are commingled with other functions of local government. Where the operations of 3—6 ------- water systems are not fiscally discrete within multi-purpose local governments, there is no means of ensuring optimal pricing and production decisions for water supply. In the commingled setting, outcomes will be optimal only in cases where the weights assigned to the multiple attributes of public water supply are the same as those that would be produced when the water supply “objective function” is considered by itself. Commingled budgeting precludes establishment of a rational relationship between the reve ues generated by the water system and its level of expenditure. When revenues are contributed to a jurisdiction’s general fund, the water system is left to compete for funding along with other public needs through a process unrelated to the amount of revenue generated by water rates. The separation of revenues from expenditures produces not only arbitrary and suboptimal patterns of expenditure, but arbitrary pricing polici as well. General fund financing creates an air of uncertainty- which fosters a misperception that a relationship exists be?Jeen the cost of the service and the level of service provided. In this regard, water supply is generally regarded as an excellent bargain because of the historical trend towards underpricing. Privately Owned Water Systems In 45 states, privately owned water systems must obtain approval for rate increases from state public utility commissions (PUCs). Conventional principles of public utility regulation would be expected to establish a full-cost basis in the relationship between prices, costs, and revenues. Ideally, this would permit privately owned water systems to apply appropriate weights to the multiple attributes of water supply in their production decisions. In practice, however, there are flaws in the rate regulation process and, in particular, flaws in its application to water utilities. There are two major classes of privately owned water systems: 1) investor owned systems which have professional management; and 2) small systems without professional management belonging to homeowner associations, trailer parks, and similar non-municipal 9 Goldstein, J., “Full-Cost Water Pricing,” Journal of the American Water Works Association , February 1986. 10 Buchanan, J.M., Public Finance In A Democratic Process , Chapel Hill, University of North Carolina Press, 1967. 11 Mueller, D.C., Public Choice , Cambridge University Press, 1979., p. 90. 3—7 ------- entities. In general, investor-owned systems tend to be successful in negotiating rate increases with the PUCs, while the smaller private systems are poorly equipped to prepare or defend rate proposals and, as a result, often do not even apply for rate increases. The problems inherent in PUC regulation of small water systems have been the subject of a number of recent studies by the National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) under sponsorship of the National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUc). One set of findings confirms that the PUC regulatory process has presented a number of barriers in its application to small water utilities. First, the total dollar value of water utilities under commission jurisdiction is est ated to be less than one percent of the total for all utilities. The procedures required of large gas, electric, and telephone utilities in rate cases are clearly out of proportion to small water utilitie 60 percent of which have annual revenues of less than $15,000. Yet water utilities are present in significant numbers, accounting for 34 percent of all regulated utilities and 43 percent of all rate cases in 1981. The N RRI studies have identif led strategies for improving the regu- latory process used by numerous states. A second finding of the NRRI studies, however, is that small water system problems do not result entirely from complex rate setting. Many small systems are simply not viable economic enti- ties. Preventing future creation of such systems and encouraging existing ones to be absorbed by larger systems may be the only long-term solutions. A Model of “Perfect” Public Choice In evaluating the performance of markets, economic theory relies on the hypothetical concept of “perfect” markets, or “perfectly competitive” markets. Among other conditions, perfect competition requires that there be no monopoly power among suppliers and that all participants possess “perfect information.” It is useful to envision how a “perfect” public choice process might apply to water supply. An appropriate model of perfect public choice for delivery 12 Lawton, R. and Davis, V., Commission Regulation f Small Water Utilities: Some Issues and Solutions , May 1983, The National Regulatory Research Institute, Columbus, Ohio. 13 Mann, P., Dreese, R., Tucker, M., Commission Regulation of Small Water Utilities: Mergers and Acquisitions , October 1986, The National Regulatory Research Institute, Columbus, Ohio. 3—8 ------- of local public services has been presented. 14 Assuming perfect information, it might be possible to accurately ascertain consumer preferences through the vehicle of an insurance sale. A water system would offer consumers a choice between two types of insurance policies relating to the need to install a new treatment process for removal of contaminants. The first type of policy would insure those concerned about increases in their water bills against such losses in the event that the decision is made to purchase a new treatment process. The second type of policy would insure those concerned, about their health against damages incurred from the contaminants if the water utility decides not to install the new treatment process. Consumers wishing to hedge could purchase some of each type of insurance, thus revealing their mixed preferences. Those electing not to participate would reveal their indifference; they would not be “free riders,” however, as their abstinence would directly affect their welfare. In arriving at its decision, the water system would determine which insurance policy generated the greatest revenue. The proceeds of the insurance sale would be used to pay the claims of the losers, making the outcome “pareto optimal” in that no one would be made worse off. Upon closer scrutiny, flaws exist in this model of “perfect” public choice. Determining the correct insurance premiums to charge is a difficult problem, for example. However, the insurance strategy for revealing consumer preferences highlights a crucial point. The optimal level of service in public water supply depends ultimately upon the level of certainty desired by consumers and the extent of their willingness to pay an extra premium for certainty - - for the privilege of being able to “take it for granted” that the water is safe to drink. It is the willingness to pay for an extra margin of safety that is critical to optimal decisioninaking. Not only is it difficult to assess preferences at such a margin, local decisioninaking processes are not capable of excluding other external factors from affecting this public choice at the margin. Thus, regulatory intervention is necessary to establish uniform goals for the level of safety to be achieved. The SDWA instructs EPA to establish drinking water standards at levels that will avoid adverse effects on the health of persons and allow for a margin of safety. This regulatory mandate is thus well-designed to address the central flaw that has been identified in local public choice processes. 14 Thompson, E. A., “A Pareto Optimal Group Decision Process,” in G. Tu].lock, ed. Papers on Non-Market Decision Makin , Univ. of Virginia: Charlottesville, 1966, pp.133—40. 3—9 ------- 3.4 Consideration of Requlatory Alternatives EPA has proposed the IOC regulations in accordance with the requirements of the SDWA Amendments of 1986. The SDWA mandates that EPA publish maximum contaminant level goals (MCLGs) and promulgate national prim r drinking water regul ions (NPDWR) for 83 specific contaminants prior to June, 1989. All inorganic contaminants evaluated in this document are included or have been added to this list. National Primary Drinking Water Regulations under the SDWA are to also include monitoring requirements. Specifically, the Act requires that “...there must be criteria and standards to assure a supply of drinking water which dependably complies with such maximum contaminant levels; including quality control and testing procedures to insure compliance with such leve1 7 and to insure proper operation and maintenance of the system...” Protection of Water Sources Versus Remedial Action As an alternative to setting standards governing the level to which contaminants must be removed prior to potable use, EPA could devise actions to protect water sources from contamination by inorganic chemicals. Such a strategy, emphasizing prevention rather than remediation, could be developed using various EPA, USDA, and FDA authorities. However, it is unlikely that any strategy for protecting water sources could be implemented effectively without relying on some reference levels of contam- ination such as MCLGs and MCLs, related to the risk of adverse health effects. Nevertheless, considerable attention has been focused on groundwater protection recently. EPA has developed a Groundwater Protection Strategy and a national Wellhead Protection Program. In addition, the need for comprehensive legislation to address this issue has been recognized. The general structure of these initia- tives are discussed below. 15 The 83 contaminants are listed in the Advance Notices of Proposed Rulemaking at 47 . 45502 (March 4, 1982) and 48 Fed. .g. 45502 (October 5, 1983). Section 1412 (b). 17 SDWA Section 1401 (1) (D). 3—10 ------- The Groundwater Protection Strateqy In an August 1984 report entitled Groundwater Protection Strateqy , the Office of Groundwater Protection (OGWP) outlined the Agency’s overall strategy for addressing groundwater policy issues. Thus far, the most important effect of the groundwater protection strategy has been to increase the quality and quantity of information available regarding the condition of the nation’s groundwater resources. This information has been used extensively in creating the framework for guiding EPA groundwater programs. The Agency recognizes the need for consistency, as well as a need to take current quality and vulnerability into account when developing protection and clean-up programs to be used by the various EPA programs. As a first step toward achieving these goals, the Agency published a report entitled Guidelines for Groundwater Classification Under the EPA Groundwater Protection Strateqy in December, 1986. The classification system outlined in the document consists of three levels representing a ground- water’s relative “value” based on its current quality, vulner- ability to contamination, and uses. Development of Welihead Protection Programs Designating protection areas around drinking water wells is one way to protect groundwater supplies. Application of this concept is common in Europe. At least 11 European countries, including Germany, Switzerland, and the Netherlands have designated zones around their public water supplies. Within these zones, special controls are imposed on any number of potential hazards. A growing number of states and municipalities in this country also are beginning to create such welihead protection areas. Depending on the nature of the contaminants involved, welihead protection areas range in size anywhere from a distance of a few hundred feet to several miles from wells. The hydrogeologic characteristics of the aquifer, the extent of pumping, and the degree of development and activity surrounding the well are the primary criteria by which protection areas are delineated. Management actilties commonly employed within these protection areas include regulation of land use through special ordinances and permits, prohibition of specified activities, and acquisition of land. Provisions for welihead protection were adopted as part of the reauthorization of the SDWA Amendments of 1986. This legislation established a nationwide program to encourage states to develop systematic and comprehensive programs to prevent contamination of public water supply wells and weilfields within their jurisdictions. Historically, states have primary responsibility for ground- water management. The Wellhead Protection Program was enacted to both enhance state programs already underway, and to encourage other states to begin such protection programs by providing 3—il ------- financial and technical assistance. The SDWA specifies that all states will participate; however, the EPA has no authority to establish a Wellhead Protection Program if a state chooses to forgo action on its own. There are no EPA sanctions against states that do not participate. The Need for Comprehensive Groundwater Legislation In a 1984 report entitled Protecting the Nation’s Groundwater from Contamination , the Office of Technology Assessment (OTA) identified some 16 Federal statutes as containing groundwater protection language but dismissed these laws as generally inadequate. Inefficient regulations and a historical lack of program funding were cited by OTA as contributing to a non- preventive approach to groundwater protection. Due to the high costs associated with groundwater clean-up technologies, OTA advised the Federal government to take a preventive approach. The National Groundwater Policy Forum, an organization sponsored jointly by the Conservation Foundation and the National Governors’ Association, released a report in November, 1985 describing Federal and state efforts to protect groundwater as fragmented. The group stated that “...Because many of the laws were written at different times and for different purposes, they often dd up to a program of groundwater protection that is neither coherent nor consistent, even if those laws are implemented to the limits of the enacted authority.” Like OTA, the Forum has called for a more preventive approach to groundwater protection. Alternatives Considered in Developing Inorganic Chemical Regulations Since the proposed standards and monitoring requirements have been mandated by statute, EPA is limited in its consideration of alternative regulatory approaches and strategies for implementation of the SDWA. EPA does not have the flexibility to consider taking “no action,” nor can the Agency propose that states establish the necessary standards and monitoring requirements based on Federal guidance. Under these constraints, the Agency is comint ted to setting explicit MCLs as close to the MCLG “as is feasible” since 18 ”Feasjble” is defined in Section 1412 (b) (5) of the SDWA as achievable through “...the use of best technology, treatment techniques and other means which the Administrator finds. . .are available (taking costs into consideration).” In addition, the Administrator must determine if “...it is economically and techno- logically feasible to ascertain the level of a contaminant in public water supplies” before setting an MCL (SDWA Section 1401 (1) (C)) 3—12 ------- analytical methods have been identified and deemed available for all contaminants. At least two MCL alternatives were evaluated for each contami- nant. Generally, these alternatives corresponded to concentrations equal to the MCLG, more, stringent than the MCLG, and/or less stringent than the MCLG. 9 In addition, for those contaminants which are currently regulated, MCL alternatives equivalent to the interim standards were evaluated. Exhibit 3-2 summarizes the MCL alternatives which were evaluated for each inorganic chemical contaminant. E IBIT 3-2 MCL Alternatives for lOCs (ug/l) More Less Interim Containin 8 t Stringent Proposed Stringent Standard Asbestos N/A 7 nil. N/A N/A Barium 100,1500,2000 5000 N/A 1000 Cadmium 0.1 5 50 10 Chromium 10 100 1000 50 Mercury 21 0.2,3 2 4,10 2 Nitrate 100,1000 10,000 N/A 10,000 Selenium 5 50 100 10 Alternatives and Basis for Monitoring Requirements EPA developed and examined several alternative sets of mon- itoring and reporting requirements for the IOC regulations. The monitoring and reporting alternatives and the basis for the options selected for each rule are discussed in the Information Collection Request (ICR) submitted for the proposed rule. The ICRs are 19 Alternatjve MCLs were obtained from Memorandum from Joe Cotruvo dated June 13, 1985 and entitled “Phase II Regulatory Impact Analysis Assumptions.” 20 Concentration in fibers 10 un or longer/liter. 21 No impacts were evaluated for nitrite standards under the assumption that additional incremental impacts beyond those calculated for nitrate would be negligible. 3—13 ------- submitted in accordance with the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1980. Costs associated with the preferred monitoring alternative were estimated and are presented in Chapter 4. In developing monitoring requirements for lOCs, EPA considered which level of government was most appropriate and provided con- siderable discretion to state regulatory agencies for determining precise monitoring standards based on local conditions. Further, to take into account the complexities of collecting representative samples in individual systems, and the potential for variability of water quality over time in surface and ground water systems, the following variables were considered in developing monitoring options: o Nu4er of samples to be taken: o Frequency of sampling; o Location of sampling points; o Which systems should sample; o When compositing of samples should be allowed; and, o When the sampling should be performed. As noted in Chapter 2, impacts of monitoring requirements for contaminants related to corrosion of plumbing and distribution system materials ..e., lead and copper) are evaluated in a separate document. EPA, Office of Drinking Water, 1988. Draft Re u1atory Impact Analysis of Proposed National Primary Drinking Water Recrulatjons for Lead and Copper . 3—14 ------- 4. ASSESSMENT OF COSTS 4.1 Introduction This chapter presents the results of analyses of cost impacts of regulatory alternatives for controlling lOCs in drinking water. The sections below describe the major assumptions that were used in the analyses, and present estimates for treatment and waste disposal costs along with a discussion of the uncertainty assoc- iated with those estimates. Finally, cost estimates for compliance monitoring and unregulated contaminant monitoring are presented along with a discussion of the monitoring requirements for public water supplies. 4.2 Major Assum tjons Used in Cost Estimates •Three critical assumptions serve as the basis for the cost estimates presented in this chapter. First, it is necessary to avoid misallocation of costs associated with current regulations to those resulting from the proposed revisions. With the exception of asbestos and nitrite, all contaminants evaluated in this document are currently regulated under interim standards. It was assumed that no impacts are attributable to revised drinking water MCLs set equal to or greater than those currently in place. Under this assumption, it is therefore necessary to determine incremental impacts for contaminants having MCL alternatives below the current standards. That is, to estimate the impacts to only those systems affected at concentrations between the proposed revised MCL and the current, interim MCL. At the most stringent (i.e., lowest) MCL alternatives, an assessment of net incremental cost impacts is necessary for all lOCs evaluated. At proposed MCL alternatives (ike., those cor- responding most closely with proposed MCLG5 for most contaminants), it is estimated that net incremental costs will result for only cadmium. The second major assumption concerns the consolidation of occurrence data across different system size categories. In developing estimates of occurrence probabilities, raw survey data from several (or in some cases all) size categories were combined and analyzed as a group. As mentioned in Chapter 2, this procedure resulted in invariant occurrence probabilities across system size categories for lOCs (see Appendix II). However, because the esti- mates are based on sampling data from finished water, and since systems serving greater than 50,000 persons generally have more effective treatment processes, more comprehensive monitoring, and a much higher level of operator expertise in place, it may be inappropriate to assume that larger systems have the same likelihood of occurrence as smaller systems. 4— ]. ------- Assuming even minute occurrence probabilities in large systems may have a large impact on cost estimates. The cost model is structured such that the application of any occurrence probability greater than zero results in the calculation of at least some “fraction” of a large system being affected. This, in turn, may lead to the overestimation of aggregate impacts since unit costs for treatment technologies and average population served in large systems are high. For these reasons, it was assumed that bC occurrence in large systems is probably negligible relative to that in smaller systems. This is supported by FRDS data which indicate that as of 1986, only 18 large systems were re orted out of compliance for all interim bc regulations combined (see Exhibit 4-1). The summary tables presented in Appendix III for each contaminant provide estimates of total costs both including and excluding occurrence in systems serving greater than 50,000 persons. Finally, as discussed in Chapter 2, occurrence data on mercury in surface water systems is subject to extreme uncertainty. Fo this reason, cost estimates which include mercury occurrence estimates, as well as estimates using the assumption that mercury occurrence is zero are presented in Exhibit 4-2, and in the summary table in Appendix III. 4.3 Treatment Costs for bOCs Draft estimates of aggregate national treatment costs for proposed alternative MCLs for lOCs are based on individual results for six contaminants: barium, cadmium, chromium, mercury, nitrate, and selenium. Because “nitrite levels in tdr nking] water are considered to be negligible relative to nitrate,” and due to nitrite’s tendency to be oxidized to nitrate during disinfection, it was assumed that incremental impacts of the nitrite regulation beyond those calculated for nitrate would be negligible and no further analyses were performed for this chemical. Although approximately 609 systems nationwide were estimated to have asbestos concentrations in excess of 7 MFL, it is assumed that treatment and waste disposal costs for this contaminant will not be attributable to this rule based on the following rationale. Natural and anthropogenic contamination of source waters is 1 0f these, 12 were violations of the nitrate standard. 2 Science Applications International Corporation, 1987. Estimated National Occurrence and Exposure to Nitrate/Nitrite in public Drinking Water Supplies (Revised Draft) . 4—2 ------- EXHIBIT 4—i FRDS IOC Violations in Community Water Systems Serving More than 50,000 persons Number of FRDS Violations bC Groundwater Surface Water Total Barium o 0 0 Cadmium 0 1 1 Chromium 1 1 2 Mercury 0 2 2 Nitrate 4 8 12 Selenium 0 1 1 Total 5 13 18 * Source: SAIC Draft Occurrence Documents for Inorganic Chemicals 4—3 ------- EXHIBIT 4—2 Emtimated Ireateent and Waste Disposal Costs at Most Stringent MCI Alternatives 1 .2 .1 Treatsent Costs Waite Costs lotal Cost5 Asnsaliied Costs it mfyrl Womber 0 c c l : Systems 1 Capital Ott Capital DIM Capital OtC Ccntamisaot tog/Il : Altucted I 45 m l U m/yrl 8 ml 15 u/yr t I I m l 1 m/yrt 4 32 51 4 12 Estimated Cotts at Moat Strinqeot MCI.s Barium I C C 6 ,713 2,090 206 : 2,032 I i ? - 4,122 313 - - — - - - Cadmium 0 I l 7 60 : 196 lB 121 7 323 23 : - - - - — - Chromium 10 : 1323 765 76 572 46 1 1,337 (74 - - - - - - :Mercarr 02: 1,376: 1,206 137 234 16 1,440 iss: -- - - — - Witratetfitrile too : 108,227 22,355 3,456 : (2,536 611 : 34611 4,057 - - - - - - Setenism S : 1713 : 4 09 4) 617 42 : loll 69 : - - - - — - Octal : 120114 3 27,001 3,942 0 16,113 651 43,114 4,793 1 - - - - — - total less Ileecury 1 118,73.6 1 25,795 3,605 1 15,939 633 1 41,754 4636 I — - - - - - Estimated Costs ol torrent MCLs Promulgated lJsder NIPOWI :Oariuu 1,000: 19: 5 3 : 5 0 1 10 i: - - - - - - :Cadoium I I I 166: 39 4: 31 2: io i:-- - - - — thromios 3 0: 20: 19 21 9 I l 2) 21-- - — - - I Mercury 2 : 445 : 553 67 1 99 9 : 652 71 : - - - - - - Wmtrateflti trite 10,000 2,577 1 469 6) : 264 12 1 733 79 1 - - — - - — iSelesiom it: (851 45 5 : 3 0 1 46 5: - - - - - — total : 3,364 1 1,130 141 : 410 24 1 1,540 (65 1 — — — — - — total less Mercury : 2,939: 577 79 1 311 IS : 686 94 - — - - - — Emtimated Wet Incremental Costs at Most Stringent MCL5 Oarioa : 6,694 1 2,065 205 : 7,027 137 1 4,112 342 1 6 (6 671 130 Cadmium : 5 ) 2: 157 14: 96 5: 253 19: 36 39 43: Chro.iom 1 1,303 1 141 76 : 564 43 : 1,310 121 1 209 276 745 1 Mercury 9351 653 1 5: 135 9: 706 641 (37 :47 156: Witratu/Witnte 1 105,700 21,866 3,389 12,212 589 1 34,156 3,9)6 1 6,273 6,717 7,700 Selesins 1 1,529 1 364 42 : o9 42 1 1,033 64 1 153 :67 62 total 1 116,130 1 25,871 3901 1 15,165 627 1 41,634 4,628 7,426 7,969 8,556 total lean rcory 115,797 I 25,216 3,126 15,628 I I I 1 40,846 4,544 t 7,289 7,622 6,400 I I lnciudes community and san-transient son-community mater eyntemi serving tune than 50,000 people fur elI coituminasts emcept #itralelWitrite. Witeate/Witrite estimatui include all psblec mater muppliet serving temer than 50,000 people. 2 Costs eipsemsed in 1966 Dollars and ore asnualeued over 20 yeaei. 3 61 most strio tnt MCL altereativem therm- may be significant co—occurrence ol lOCu ------- expected only in surface water systems in restricted areas of the country (i.e., primarily California and Washington state). These systems will also be subject to the requirements of the Surface Water Treatment Rule (SWTR) which will be in place prior to promulgation of the IOC rule. Filtration technologies installed to comply with the SW’TR will also be effective for removal of asbestos from source waters and would therefore largely subsume any treatment costs for removal which would otherwise be incurred under the IOC Rule. Corrosion of asbestos/cement (A/C) pipes in distribution systems has been shown to be another significant source of asbestos contamination in drinking water. Although a large number of public water supplies use A/C pipe, corrosivity problems in virtually all water systems nationwide will be mitigated through implementation of the corrosion control provisions promulgated in conjunction with the NPDWR for Lead/Copper/Corrosion Control. It is assumed that reducing the corrosivity of the water toward lead and copper will also be effective in eliminating corrosion of A/C pipe. While it is not possible to predict precisely, it is assumed that the number of systems for which additional, centralized treatment will be necessary (beyond that adopted for the SWTR and the corrosion control rule) for control of asbestos will be negligible and no further cost analyses were conducted for this contaminant. The basic algorithm utilized in obtaining estimates for total national costs associated with treatment is relatively straightforward. For each system size category, for both ground and surface water systems, the number of systems with contamination above a given MCL alternative is estimated according to the methodology described in Chapter 2. These estimates are then merged with a compliance decision matrix which predicts the relative likelihood of a system of a given size and source choosing various treatment technologies or other compliance options (see Appendix IV). These matrices represent a consensus based on the best judgement of professional engineers, WMA analysts, and EPA staff. The result of these procedures is to provide an estimate of the number of affected systems that would use each treatment/com- pliance option nationwide. These estimates are then mult4.plied by the appropriate unit costs for each technology or option detailed in the CIT documents (see Appendix V). Exhibit 4-2 presents a summary of net incremental treatment and waste disposal costs associated with the most stringent MCL alternative for each contaminant in systems serving less than 4—5 ------- 50,000 persons. 3 Cost estimates are in 1986 dollars and were annualized using social discount rates of three, five, and seven percent over 20 years. Net incremental capital costs associated with the most stringent MCL alternatives would be approximately $40.8 billion, excluding mercury. The incremental operation and maintenance costs are approximately $4.5 billion per year, resulting in annualized costs of between $7.2 billion and $8.4 billion. Two important factors should be noted regarding the cost estimates at the most stringent MCL alternatives, however. First, the concentrations used for regulatory alternatives are less than the PQLs for several contaminants. As such, these estimates reflect impacts that would occur only if standards were set below thresholds of readily achievable quantification and discernable adverse health effects. Second, these costs may represent an overestimate insofar as the “double counting” of costs in systems with multiple occurrence has not been taken into account. Due to these two caveats, these estimates should be used for comparison purposes only. Because of its ubiquitous presence at low concentrations, and because all CWS and NCWS are assumed to be subject to the nitrate/nitrite regulation, the vast majority of the annualized costs (83 percent) are attributable to these substances at the most stringent MCL alternatives. Net incremental costs associated with the proposed MCL alternatives for systems serving less than 50,000 persons are presented in Exhibit 4—3. Capital costs at the preferred MCL alternatives are approximately $73 million, with O&M costs of $6 million per year. This results in annualized costs of between $11 million and $13 million per year depending on the discount rate applied. Appendix III contains cost summary tables for each contaminant at all MCL alternatives at which occurrence was noted. It should be noted that the estimates provided in the Appendix III tables are cumulative and therefore include costs associated with systems having contaminant levels exceeding the current stand- ards. For this reason, the costs presented in the tables for the interim MCLs (i.e., cadmium at 10 ugh) must be subtracted from the corresponding costs presented in the tables for the proposed 3 As described in Chapter 2, it is probable that occurrence estimated in systems serving more than 50,000 persons was an artifact of the method used to estimate occurrence. Under the assumption that occurrence in these systems is zero, the estimates in Exhibits 4—2 and 4—3 represent WMA’s “best” estimates. 4 Unhike the co-occurrence estimates presented in Chapter 2, it is possible that co-occurrence at the most stringent MCL alternatives may be significant. 4—6 ------- EXIIIBIT 4—3 Wotiaated treataest sod Waite Phapoaai Costa at Proposed MCI. literaatie,a Teeniest Cost. Waste Cost. 3 : total Coats 3 ;oonualised Coats ($ a/pr) 3 : Pushers :: : : MC I Spates, Capital 008 : Capital O I l : Capital Oil Costoaisaot lug/I) : Iffeeted I 1 ii i i a/pr) : ii . 1$ a/pr) : a .) i i a/pr) : S 30 S 5% S 7% fat iaated Coat. of Proposed ICLa Cadai na : 380: 79 8 61 1 1(3 i i :-- - - - - lstlaated Coats of Carreat WCLa Proazigated Qoder WiPDWi 4 ; Cadajua l0 i sa: 30 i: 3) 2: to 6:-- - - - - ktiaated Wet iscreseotal Costa of Proposed ICLa :Cadaioa : 192: 40 o: 33 2 73 6 Ii 12 i3 I the preferred ICLo for barioa, chroaasa, aercarp, nitrate, sod eeieeisa are greater than or .qaai to the latersa WCLo, hence the Iscreaootai lapact . of reaoel ,g these coztaaioosta are aaaeaed to he zero Nitrite occorreoce is aoeuaod to he oeglagihie, therefore so heoefsta or teeataeot aad aaate disposal coata oouid he incurred for this cootaaasaat Benefits and treataeot disposal ceat. for eabe.toa are aobaaaed bp othar drinking aster regsiatioas 2 include coaaooitp and aos-traaaieot aoa-coaauaitp aater apatesa serving less thao 50,000 people 3 Cooto are eaproooed in 1906 Dsiiara and are annualized over 21 pears ------- revised MCLs (i.e., cadmium at 5 ug/l) to obtain the incremental costs described above. In addition to the assumptions discussed in Section 4.1, several significant sources of uncertainty and a number of other assumptions made in the analysis contribute to the error inherent in the bC cost estimates. These assumptions arid sources of uncertainty are discussed below. In the Cost and Technology (C/T) documents, the Criteria and Standards Division (CSD) assumed that some contaminants would occur predominantly in either ground or surçace waters, and capital and O&M costs were developed accordingly. However, occurrence data show that some contaminants assumed (in the C/T document) to be prevalent in groundwater were in fact more predominant in surface water systems and vice versa. To compensate for this discrepancy, unit treatment cost estimates were adjusted (where necessary) according to the following procedure. Capital costs, provided as total costs in thousands of dollars, were divided by maximum daily production values provided for each system size to obtain costs per million gallons of capacity. Similarly, 0&M costs, provided as thousands of dollars per year, are divided by the product of average daily production values (in million gallons per day), 365 (days per year), and a conversion factor of 1000 to obtain costs in million dollars per million gallons of production. These adjus- ted, “per unit” costs were then incorporated into the cost model and multiplied by the applicable design flow parameters. Based on estimates of average influent concentrations of lOCs in affected systems and the proposed MCL alternatives, the percentage removal required (see Appendix II) for compliance in most syst ms will generally be less than that assumed in the C/T documents to derive unit treatment cost estimates. The cost estimates are based on the removal efficiencies which corresponded most closely to the average concentrations estimated using the Replicate model and the proposed MCL alternatives. Unit costs associated with regionalization and alternate source development were derived in the C/T documents using assumptions that resulted in unreasonably high estimates for these compliance options. These cost estimates, in turn, were used in 5 This distinction is important because costs of constructing and maintaining treatment systems may vary significantly according to source due to dissimilar design flow parameters and other factors. 6 USEPA Office of Drinking Water, Criteria and Standards Division, 1987. Cost Supplement to Technologies and Costs for Removal of Inorganic Chemicals from Potable Water Supplies . Separate document developed for each contaminant. 4—8 ------- developing compliance decision trees. Given the high cost presented, it was not considered likely that small systems would frequently choose these options. Instead, higher probabilities were assigned to centralized treatment. Lower cost assumptions for alternate source (e.g., the cost of drilling a well), and corresponding adjustment of the compliance decision trees would result in a decrease in total national costs for the smallest four system size categories. A sensitivity analysis was conducted to evaluate the effect of this parameter on annualized treatment cost estimates. It was determined that altering these inputs to reflect more realistic assumptions will decrease annualized treatment costs by less than ten percent and would therefore be well within the bounds of uncertainty described in Section 4.4 below. Two sets of unit cost estimates were developed by CSD for most central treatment options. The low cost estimates, which assume that no special pretreatment of source water is necessary for effective removal of lOCs, were used as inputs for the ATm runs. The high cost estimates incorporate costs for such practices as softening and filtration as pretreatment to optimize bC removal in waters with high turbidity and/or hardness. Because the struc- ture of the decision trees already incorporates the likelihood of installation of filtration technologies for compliance with the Surface Water Treatment Rule, it was assumed that the portion of the “high” unit costs associated with filtration as a pretreatment would not apply to surface water systems. For groundwater systems, a similar assumption was made since turbidity is naturally very low. It was then possible to estimate the portion of the high cos estimates associated only with hardness removal as a pretreatment. These costs were assumed to represent the net difference between the high and low unit cost estimates. Although it was not possible to estimate the number of systems to which these “high” unit cost estimates would apply, compliance costs may be slightly higher in systems affected with bC contamination that also have to pretreat to control hardness. Some uncertainty is also associated with costs for the use of point-of-use (POTJ) devices as a compliance option for lOCs. Although the cost and technology documents provide estimates for POU, the decision trees assume that the only acceptable non- centralized compliance option will be point-of-entry (POE) devices. Nevertheless, the POU costs were used as a surrogate for this option. Finally, the cost estimates associated with the least expensive POU technology were used in this analysis. Because a very small portion of total costs are associated with the possible use of POLl/POE devices as compliance options, the error introduced by this assumption is probably negligible. 7 Malcolm Pirnie, Inc. Personal Communication, June, 1987. 4—9 ------- 4.4 Waste Disposal Costs Estimates of waste disposal costs for lOCs are included in Exhibits 4-2 and 4-3 and in Appendix III. The methodology employed to derive these estimates is similar to that used in calculating treatment costs. The number of systems using each water treatment option was applied to a decision tree for waste treatment/disposal options (see Appendix IV). Through this procedure, an estimate of the number of affected systems which would choose each waste treat- ment option was derived nd multiplied by the unit waste treatment costs published by CSD. This procedure was repeated for each contaminant at each MCL alternative. Based on a review of the provisions in the current Federal regulations pertaining to hazardous waste disposal, it was assumed that process wastes are not subject to requirements for hazardous wastes under current Resource Conservation and Recovery Act (RCRA) regulations. Disposal methods included direct discharge to sanitary sewers, direct discharge into receiving waters, sanitary landfill, and land application. Since the structure of the cost model does not allow differ- entiation by source in systems affected, unit waste disposal costs for groundwater were used if the majority of systems affected were groundwater systems, and vice versa. The unit waste disposal cost data are presented as curves (see Appendix VI) and had to be tran- scribed in tabular form; some error is inherent in this procedure. In addition, no waste disposal costs were estimated for systems which would opt to modify existing central treatment for compliance since cost curves were not generated for “modification” technol- ogies. Finally, zero waste disposal costs were assumed for systems using POU, alternate source, regionalization, and GAC as treatment/compliance options. 4.5 Uncertainty in Estimates of National Costs Introduction Uncertainty calculations discussed in this section have been conducted for impacts associated only with contaminants for which incremental treatment and waste disposal costs will be incurred at the proposed MCL alternatives (i.e., those cost estimates presented in Exhibit 4-3 above). The magnitude of uncertainty associated with other cost estimates (e.g., those calculated at the most stringent MCL alternatives) may vary significantly due to the possibility of co-occurrence and other factors. 8 USEPA Office of Drinking Water Criteria and Standards Division, 1986. Technologies and Costs for the Treatment and Removal of Waste By-Products from Water Treatments for the Removal of Inorganic and Radioactive Contaminants . Revised draft. 4—10 ------- Methodoloqy There is a degree of uncertainty inherent in any estimate of compliance costs. This uncertainty arises from the fact that only a small number of observations are available for many of the factors that contribute to overall costs. These factors include the following: o The frequency and degree of contamination from any given chemical: o The likelihood that a system will select a particular treatment technology; and, o The unit costs of available treatment technologies. The errors in the estimates of these input variables form the basis of the overall uncertainty computed for compliance costs. The form of the fundamental equation underlying the cost calculation facilitated the estimation of the magnitude of the errors. This equation, as embodied in the ATm model is as follows: C = P 1 * N 1 * * jk * Cik ijk Where: I designates the category of water system (12 sizes times two water sources); j designates the treatment already in place; k designates the type of additional treatment selected to meet the IOC standard; P 1 is the probability that a system in the ith category exceeds the MCL for the bC in question; N 1 is the number of water systems in the ith category; is the probability that a system in the ith category will choose treatment j to meet the filtration requirement; is the probability that a system with treatment j already in place will select treatment k to meet the bC standard; and, Cik is the unit cost (typically, dollars per system) of treatment k for a system in category i. (This term may represent either capital or O&M costs). 4—li ------- All of these variables except N are treated as random variables, each having a distribution with a mean value (the deterministic value used in the ATm model) and a standard error. To evaluate the product inside the summation, the following simplifying assumptions were adopted: o All random variables are approximately normally distri- buted; and, o All independent variables are uncorrelated with each other. These assumptions allow the expression of the standard error of a multiplicative equation such that if a=x*y * z where x, y, and z are approximately normally distributed with means X, Y, and Z and with standard errors Sy and S 1 then Sa can be approximated by: Sa = [ x 22 )*(sy 2 2)*(sz2+ 2) — Performing the summation requires a method for accumulating the standard errors of the internal products. To accomplish this, it was assumed that random variables to be summed were either per- fectly correlated or perfectly uncorrelated, depending on the variables in question. Although an oversimplification, this assumption eliminates the need to consider cross-correlation terms, which make the calculations extremely complex and for which no data are available. Specifically, the procedure involved the following assumptions. o Errors in the costs of similar treatments for a given bc are perfectly correlated. For example, lime softening could be used to remove a contaminant in (a) systems having no filtration in place (provided that conventional treatment or direct filtration were added), (b) those already having direct filtration, or (C) those having conventional treatment in place. This assumption means that if the cost estimate in case (a) is of f by +10 percent, then the estimates in the other two cases are also off by +10 percent. o Errors in the costs of dissimilar treatments for a given bC are perfectly uncorrelated. That is, a +10 percent error in the cost of lime softening gives no information about the error in the cost of reverse osmosis. 4—12 ------- o Within a given water source (surface or ground), errors n cost estimates across “small” system size categories (de- fined as all systems serving 3,300 people or fewer) are perfectly correlated. Similarly, errors across all “large” size categories (i.e., systems serving more that 3,300 persons) are perfectly correlated. o Errors across water sources and between “small” and “large” size categories (as defined above) are perfectly uncorrelated. o For a given system size and water source, errors in total capital costs are perfectly correlated with errors in operating and maintenance costs. These assumptions allowed the calculation of the standard error of the summed random variables x, y, and z through the following expression: a = x + y + z. The equation for the case where the errors in x, y, and z are perfectly correlated is: Sa = + S , + S . For the perfectly uncorre].ated case, the expression is: Sa = + Sy 2 + Sz 2 )’/ 2 Standard Errors of Independent Variables The formulas for estimating standard errors were implemented on a spreadsheet. Mean values for independent variables were taken from the input files for the ATh model. The errors in the probabilities of exceeding the MCLs were estimated by SAIC on the basis of sample data and a curve—fitting procedure. The other errors were estimated by staff of WMA and Malcolm Pirnie, Inc. who were responsible for generating the decision trees and unit treatment costs. The magnitudes of the standard errors of the independent variables, expressed as a percentage of their mean values, are summarized in Exhibit 4-4 below. In the interest of simplifying the calculation, the five percent error in the prob- ability of selecting a particular filtration method was ignored; a sensitivity analysis showed that it contributed less than one percent to the estimate of the standard error of national cost. 4—13 ------- EXHIBIT 4—4 Standard Errors of Independent Variables in bC Cost Calculation (As a Percent of Mean Values) Standard Error as a Decimal Fraction of the Mean Probability of a system exceeding the MCL for a given bC (Pd): Surface Ground Cadmium (MCL = 5 ug/1) (No occurrence) .43 Probability of selecting a 0.05 0.05 particular filtration treatment (Pjj) Probability of selecting a 0.15 0.15 particular ICC treatment Unit treatment cost (cik) 0.25 0.25 Standard Errors of National Costs Using the procedure described above, the standard errors of the national costs of compliance were estimated for cadmium at 5 ugh. The results are given in Exhibit 4—5. The proportions shown in the Exhibit apply to capital, O&N, and annualized costs, on the assumption that errors in capital and O&M costs are perfectly correlated. It also applies to the compliance cost (the cost of meeting the proposed MCL minus the cost of meeting the NIPDWR) under the assumption that errors in the costs of meeting the two sets of standards are perfectly correlated. Results presented in Exhibit 4-5 involve two assumptions: a) that errors between “small” and “large” systems are perfectly uncorrelated; and, b) that these errors are perfectly correlated. In the absence of better information, there is no way to choose between these two cases. The exhibit shows that the standard errors in cost range from 20 to 28 percent of the mean values for cadmium. 4—14 ------- EXHIBIT 4—5 Standard Errors in Compliance Cost Estimates (As Decimal Fractions of Mean Values) Assumption: Errors between large and small sy stems are: Compliance Cost by Contaminant: tJncorrelated Correlated Cadmium (MCL = 5 ugh) 0.204 0.284 4.6 Monitorjn Costs Monitoring cost estimates for contaminants addressed in this document are summarized in Exhi1 jt 4-6 (more detailed estimates are displayed in Appendix VII). Estimates include analytical costs for compliance monitoring averaged over an 11 year period and were derived for asbestos, barium, cadmium, chromium, mercury, nitrate, nitrite, and selenium. In addition to the compliance monitoring, costs were calculated for monitoring for the following unregulated contaminants: antimony, beryllium, cyanide, nickel, sulfate, and thallium. Monitoring cost estimates for lOCs were derived using the proposed requirements outlined in the following sources: o National Primary Drinking Water Regulations for Organic and Inorganic Contaminants and Monitoring for Unregulated Contaminants - Draft Proposal, Office of Drinking Water, January 18, 1989. o Briefing on Monitoring Requirements for Public Water Sys- tems, Office of Drinking Water, March 6, 1987. o Joseph Cotruvo, memo to Arnold Kuzmack, April 13, 1987. o Maria Gomez-Taylor memo to David Schnare, September 30, 1986. o Personal communications with Office of Drinking Water, Criteria and Standards Division. 9 As mentioned above, monitoring requirements for contaminants generally considered to be of concern due to by products of corrosion will be analyzed separately. 4—15 ------- EXHIBIT 4—6 NOTE: ALL IOC monitoring cost modeLs extend over a 11 year period. This aLLows for one initiaL round and one repeat round for aLL water systems subject to reguLation. CONTAMINANT I I ASBESTOS I I BARIUM CADMIUM I CHROMIUM MERCURY I I NITRATE I NITRITE I SELENIUM I COST OF PROPOSED MCL ALTERNATIVES (In MiLLions of 1956 DoLLars) COST OF MCL MOST STRINGENT ALTERNATIVES I MCL (ug/L) LOW HIGH MCL (ugIL) LOW HIGH 7 MFL 1.0 1.7 7 MFL 1 0 1.7 100 0.2 0.4 5,000 0.1 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.2 j 5 0 1 0 2 10 0.1 0.3 100 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.3 0.3 2 0.2 0 3 1,000 3 0 1. 4 10,000 1.3 1.4 1 ,000 1.1 1.1 I 1,000 1.1 Li 5 0.3 0.4 I 50 0 2 0.2 I I TOTAL I $6.1 CURRENT COSTS $2.0 I INCREMENTAL COSTS I $4.1 $8.8 I $4 1 $5.3 I $2.0 $2.0 $2.0 I $6.8 $2.1 $3.3 I 4—16 ------- Based on the requirements outlined in these sources, models were constructed for calculating high and low range estimates for average annual monitoring costs for each contaminant. The results of all calculations are summarized in Appendix VII for all contaminants at the various MCL alternatives evaluated. At the proposed MCL alternatives, the total average annual low bound costs (considered the “best” estimate) of compliance monitoring for these bC contaminants are estimated at $4.1 million per year while the high bound costs are estimated to be $5.3 million per year. Total costs of unregulated contaminant monitoring under the rule are estimated to range from $0.2 million to $1.6 million as a one time cost. Like the procedure for estimating treatment and waste disposal costs, it was necessary to subtract current monitoring costs attributable to the NIPDWRs for these contaminants to obtain the estimates of incremental cost. The estimated total cost of monitoring for ten inorganic contaminants under the interim regulations is reported in the Pub ic Water System Supervision Program (PWSSP) ICR as $3.3 million. Of the ten inorganics which are currently regulated, six contaminants are addressed in the proposed regulation and evaluated in this document. It is esti- mated that, of the total costs of IOC compliance monitoring under the interim regulations, $2.0 m lion is attributable to monitor- ing for these six contaminants. Using this figure, incremental monitoring costs for lOCs are estimated at $2.1 million per year under the low bound scenario, and $3.3 million per year under the high bound at the proposed MCL alternatives. Description of Monjtorjn Requirements The EPA’s goal is to establish monitoring requirements for lOCs that will ensure compliance with the proposed NPDWRs in the most efficient manner possible. The program is intended to target monitoring efforts on contaminants most likely to be present in individual systems. This program is based on several general concepts, including: o Requiring states to conduct regular vulnerability assessments to account for changes in the potential for contamination over time; 10 lnformatjon Collection Request for the Public Water System Supervision Program , Appendix H, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Office of Drinking Water, March 13, 1986. 11 The cost estimate for the six contaminants was calculated by apportioning the total cost per sample for inorganic analyses reported in Appendix H of the PWSSP ICR for the ten contaminants. 4—17 ------- o Providing extensive discretion to states to tailor monitoring requirements based on systems’ vulnerability to various contain inants; o Allowing the use of recent monitoring data in lieu of new data, where applicable; o Allowing the use of historical monitoring data in making vulnerability determinations; o Designation of sampling schemes that allow for simultaneous monitoring for all regulated contaminants; and, o Focusing sampling on times when vulnerability is highest for contaminants that fluctuate seasonally. Under the proposed NPDWRS for inorganic chemicals, all com- munity water systems and non-transient, non—community systems would be required to perform both compliance and unregulated contaminant monitoring. In addition, all non-community water supplies would be required to perform monitoring for nitrate/nitrite. Six of the lOCs to be regulated in Phase II (i.e., asbestos, barium, cadmium, chromium, mercury, and selenium) are classified as “Tier II” con- taminants under the proposal. Tier II contaminants are of suff i- cient concern to warrant national regulation, but occur in a predictable fashion, justifying flexible national monitoring requirements to be applied by state authorities. Nitrate and nitrite are classified as “Tier I” contaminants. Tier I contaminants occur with sufficient frequency and are of sufficient concern to warrant national regulation and consistent monitoring and reporting. The following sections discuss the proposed monitoring requirements for each of the two contaminant tiers and for the unregulated contaminants. A) Tier II The minimum monitoring requirements for barium, cadmium, chromium, mercury and selenium are as follows. Ground water systems must monitor every three years and surface water systems must monitor annually. States may reduce the monitoring frequencies to no less than every ten years if all results of at least three rounds of monitoring are less than 50 percent of the MCL. The first round of monitoring for these contaminants must be initiated within 30 days from publication of the final regulation and must be completed within 18 months from publication. Tier II monitoring requirements for metals are summarized graphically in Exhibit 4—7. States will base their decision on monitoring frequencies for each system on various factors, including: 1) reported levels from 4—18 ------- EXHIBIT 4—7 INORGANIC CHEMICALS* Proposed Monitoring Requirements I I Surface Water Annually * Regulations cover Barium, Cadmium. Chromium. Mercury, and Selenium One or More Previous Analytical Results 50% of MCL Ground Water Every 3 Years Initial Three Rounds of Monitoring All Previous Analytical Results < 50% of MCL -‘- Repeat Monitoring No Less Than Every 10 (State Discretion) T Ground Water Every 3 Years I Surface Water Annually I ------- previous monitoring data; 2) the degree of variation reported in the source waters; and 3) other factors that may affect contaminant levels, such as changes in pumping rates for ground water supplies and changes in stream flows. Surface water systems will sample at points in the distribu- tion system that are representative of each source or at each entry point to the distribution system that is located after any treatment. The number of samples will be determined by the number of sources or treatment plants. Sampling will be done at entry points to the distribution systems for ground water systems and the number of samples will be determined by the number of entry points. This approach will make it easier to pinpoint possible contaminated sources within a system. In both surface and ground water systems, the proposed sampling locations are such that they may be used for the simultaneous collection of samples for other source related contaminants. The total number of samples may be reduced at state discretion by the use of composite samples. Composite samples of up to five sources or entry points would be allowed. If the concentration in the composite sample indicates that one or more of the individual samples may exceed the MCL, follow-up sampling would be required at each sampling point included in the composite. If the result of one analysis exceeds the MCL for a given contaminant, the system is in non-compliance and procedures for public notification must be followed. States have the discretion to require that a confirmation sample be collected within two weeks at the same sampling location to verify the original finding. In this case, if the average of the two samples analyzed exceed the MCL, the system is in noncompliance and procedures for public notification must be followed. The state may specify additional monitoring beyond the federally mandated minimum requirements for such systems. B) Tier II: Asbestos The EPA is proposing that only vulnerable systems that may have high levels of asbestos fibers greater than 10 urn in length monitor for asbestos. States will have the discretion to determine which systems are considered vulnerable for asbestos based on: 1) potential contamination of the water source; 2) the use of asbes- tos-cement pipes for finished water distribution; 3) the corro- sivity of the water; and, 4) the potential that the concentration of fibers greater than 10 urn might approximate 7 MFL. The compliance monitoring requirements for asbestos will include a one-time monitoring round for all vulnerable systems. Sampling will be conducted at the entry points to the distribution system if the contamination is due to raw water quality, or at 4—20 ------- representative points in the distribution system if contamination is due to asbestos-cement pipe. Both potential sources of contamination may be considered for some systems, requiring that samples be collected both at entry points to the distribution system and at the tap. The minimum number of samples collected will be one sample per source or treatment plant for surface water supplies and one sample per entry point to the distribution system for groundwater supplies. The repeat monitoring requirements for systems with results not exceeding 50 percent of the MCL will be required at the discretion of the states. For systems with results exceeding 50 percent of the MCL, repeat monitoring will be required every three years for ground water systems and annually for surface water systems. The confirmation of positive results will be the same as previously discussed for other Tier II inorganics. EPA is also proposing that the completion period for the initial round of compliance monitoring for asbestos be extended to five years, because of the limited laboratory capabilities currently available to conduct asbestos analysis. Asbestos monitoring requirements are summarized in Exhibit 4-8. C) Tier I EPA is proposing minimum monitoring requirements for Tier I lOCs (i.e., nitrate and nitrite) that are more stringent than the proposed monitoring requirements for Tier II inorganics. Mon- itoring requirements for nitrate/nitrite monitoring are summarized in Exhibit 4-9. Initially, the sampling frequency for community and non- transient non-community systems will be quarterly for surface water systems and annually for ground water systems. Both surface and ground water systems must monitor quarterly whenever any previous result exceeded 50 percent of the MCL. Quarterly monitoring may be reduced to annual monitoring when results from four consecutive quarters are less than 50 percent of the MCL. Transient non-community water systems must monitor every 3 years for ground water systems and annually for surface water systems. Sampling should be conducted during periods of high vulnerability (e.g., after rainfall or fertilizer application). The sampling locations and the minimum number of samples would be as previously described for Tier II, source-related inorganics. If the result of any analysis exceeds the MCL for nitrate or nitrite, a second sample must be collected within 24 hours and analyzed within two weeks. If the average of the two samples exceeds the MCL, or if the system fails to analyze a follow-up 4—21 ------- EXHIBIT 4—8 ASBESTOS Proposed Monitoring Requirements <50% of MCL Repeat Monitoring at State Discretion 4—22 ------- EXHIBIT 4-9 NITRATE I NITRITE Proposed Monitoring Requirements Community and Non-Transient Non-Community Systems : Ground Water Systems Surface Water Systems Monitor Quarterly Monitor Annually Any result ? 50% of MCL All results <50% of MCL - Transient Non-Community Systems : Surface Water Systems Monrtor Annually 4 Consecutive Quarters with Results <50% of MCL No 4 Consecutive’ Quarters with Results <50% of MCL Ground Water Systems Monitor Every 3 Years 4—23 ------- sample, the system will be deemed in non- ompliance and procedures for public notification must be followed. At state discretion, cornpositinq of up to five source or entry points may be allowed. Like Tier II contaminants, if the concentration in the composite sample indicates that one or more of the individual samples may exceed the MCL, follow-up sampling would be required at each sampling point included in the composite. D) Unrequlated Contaminants EPA is proposing monitoring requirements for six inorganic chemicals (i.e., antimony, beryllium, cyanide, nickel, sulfate, and thallium) for which MCLs have not yet been proposed. Monit- oring requirements for these unregulated contaminants will apply only to those systems the state finds vulnerable to contamination. States will have the discretion to apply these monitoring re- quirements based on local concerns and priorities. The proposed regulation involves one round of sampling in which groundwater systems will collect one sample at each entry point which is located after any treatment to the distribution system. Surface water systems may sample at points in the distribution system that are representative of each source or at each entry point to the distribution system which is located after any treatment. Composite samples representative of up to five entry points for groundwater systems or five sources for surface water systems are allowed at state discretion. Assumptions Used in the Monitoring Cost Models A number of assumptions apply to monitoring costs for nitrate/nitrite, barium, cadmium, chromium, mercury, and selenium, as outlined below. o Average number of entry points for groundwater systems: System Size ( Population Served Entry Points <500 2 500—10,000 4 > 10,000 6 o Surface water systems average one source per system. o One sample is taken per source or entry point. 4—24 ------- o Models are broken down by 12 standardized system size cate- gories (see Chapter 2), by community and non-transient non- community systems (for nitrate and nitrite, all non- community water systems are included), and by source. o There will be no phase-in for the initial round of moni- toring on the basis of system size. o Systems would be required to take one confirmation sample each time a source or entry point tested above the MCL. o Systems without occurrence of Tier II contaminants above the MCLs would be allowed to conduct repeat monitoring every 10 years. o systems with occurrence of Tier II contaminants above the MCLs would be required to conduct repeat monitoring annually for surface water and every three years for ground water systems. o At the most stringent MCL alternatives for the Tier II contaminants, it was assumed that all systems with any occurrence would be required to monitor annually for surface water systems and every three years for ground water systems. o All systems with resuJ . s less than the practical quantitation limit (PQL) would be allowed to submit composite samples each time monitoring was conducted. o Monitoring for Tier I contaminants was modeled based on a simplifying assumption that the initial monitoring results would determine frequencies in subsequent rounds of monitoring. Thus, a ground water system with initial results greater than 50 percent of the MCL would be assumed to monitor quarterly in all subsequent rounds of monitoring. Because more current information on the average number of entry points for ground water systems was obtained after the monitoring calculations were completed, the assumption regarding entry points was updated for nitrates and nitrites (which represent the majority of monitoring costs) as presented below, but was not updated for the Tier II contaminants. The new assumption is not expected to have a significant effect on monitoring costs for the ‘I ier II contaminants; costs for these contaminants will, however, be revised for the final rule as necessary. 12 PQLs for each Phase II contaminant were provided in Exhibit 2—10. 4—25 ------- o Average number of entry points for groundwater systerrts: 13 System Size ( Population Served) Entry Points 25—100 1.0 101—500 1.5 501—1,000 2.0 1,001—3,300 2.5 3,301—10K 3.0 10,001—25K 5.0 25,001—50K 6.0 50,001—75K 8.0 75,001—500K 10.0 500,001—1M 20.0 Over iN 50.0 High and low bound models were designed for each contaminant f or the proposed and most stringent MCL’S. These models are similar except for the following assumptions. o For the low bound model, it was assumed that systems with occurrence above the MCL would be positive at only one source or entry point, and would exceed the MCL only once during the sampling period. o The high bound models assume that systems with occurrence greater than the MCL will have occurrence at each source or entry point each time monitoring is conducted. o The Tier II high bound models assume 10 percent of all systems would have inadequate historical monitoring data and would therefore be required to conduct an initial round of monitoring. The low bound model assumes five pe ent of all systems would be subject to this requirement. Analytical cost assumptions may also differ between high and low bound mode-is, as described in Exhibit 4-10 below. 13 Based on survey results included in the Final Descriptive Summary: 1986 Survey of Community Water Systems , US EPA, Office of Drinking Water, October 23, 1987. 14 Persorial Communication, Association of State Drinking Water Administrators, October, 1987. 4—26 ------- EXHIBIT 4-10 Analytical Cost Assumptions -- lOCs IOC Low High Asbestos $300 $500 Mercury, Selenium 20 25 Cadmium, Barium, Chromium 9 20 and Unregulated Contaminants Nitrate/Nitrite 10 10 The analysis of asbestos monitoring costs differs from the other lOCs as follows: o Only vulnerable systems are required to monitor. o Occurrence data by system size were not available. o Costs are estimated for community water systems only. o Only one MCL alternative exists for asbestos, therefore the cost estimate under “most stringent” is the same as “proposed”. o Monitoring will be phased in based on system size over a five year period. o The difference between the high and low bound model is based on the analytical cost only. - o The average source/entry point per system is assumed to be one. The analysis of unregulated contaminants also differs from the other lOCs as follows: o Only vulnerable systems monitor. o Monitoring is limited to one single sample. o Repeat monitoring or confirmation monitoring is entirely left to state discretion and is not estimated. 4—27 ------- o The number of entry points, sources and samples per source are assumed to be the same as those of the Tier I and II monitoring cost models. The critical assumption needed for estimating costs for unregulated contaminant monitoring is the number of systems that would be found vulnerable and would therefore be required to collect samples. Based on NIRS data for these contaminants, it was assumed that the sum of occurrence probabilities for the six lOCs considered in the analysis represented the low bound of the number of systems that the states would classify as vulnerable. This summation procedure yields an estimate of 10 percent of systems. The high bound estimate is represented by assuming that all contaminants occur as frequently as the contaminant with the highest probability of occurrence in NIRS (i.e., nickel at approximately five percent). This procedure yields an estimate of 30 percent of systems being found vulnerable. Several factors regarding the estimate of unregulated con- taminant monitoring costs should be noted. First, this methodology entails considerable uncertainty. For example, when making vulnerability determinations, how would states know which ten to 30 percent of systems have occurrence prior to an initial round of comprehensive testing? While no discrete data sets exist for estimating this component of the total national costs, EPA believes that the ten to 30 percent range represents a realistic estimate of the number of systems likely to be found vulnerable to unregulated lOCs. Second, all systems assumed to be vulnerable were assumed vulnerable for all six unregulated lOCs. This is probably an over—estimate of impacts on an individual system basis since there would be few cases where water systems would test positive for all six contaminants. Finally, since unregulated contaminant monitoring is treated as a one—time, “capital” expenditure, the total annual costs for the rule are not affected significantly regardless of whether high or low assumptions regarding occurrence probabilities are accepted. 4.7 Costs to State Programs An estimate of the total costs to state programs for the entire Phase II regulatory package (i.e., including both lOCs and synthetic organic chemicals) is included in the draft Regulatory Impart Analysis for Synthetic Organic Chemicals. 4—28 ------- 5. ASSESSMENT OF BENEFITS 5.1 “ Damages Avoided” Versus Total Benefits Computation of avoided health damages has been the conventional approach used in quantifying benefits of improved drinking water regulations. In considering the “total benefits” of improved drinking water regulations, it is appropriate to incorporate a broader range of effects on social welfare than the quantifiable avoidance of adverse health effects. There are two additional categories of benefits that cannot be assessed in a quantitative fashion but must nonetheless be recognized as benefits, even if only as “intangibles.” First, there are benefits which result from the fact that drinking water standards incorporate a margin of safety. Secondly, indirect benefits appear likely to result from efficiency improvements in the water industry that may be induced by the expense of SDWA compliance. This chapter addresses the economic benefits of controlling bC contamination in public drinking water supplies. Section 5.2 and 5.3 discuss the above identified categories of “intangible” benefits. Section 5.4 presents estimates of quantifiable benefits. 5.2 Benefits of A Margin of Safety The safety of public water supplies has historically been “taken for granted,” implying the risk perceived by consumers is negligibly small. Thus, there is an implied “warranty” inherent in the nature of public water supply which provides additional benefits beyond the expected value of avoided adverse health effects. There are two types of additional benefits provided by the warranty: benefits in consumption and benefits in production. Consumption benefits are those whose immediate beneficiaries are individuals in their capacities as consumers; production benefits are those whose immediate ben ficiaries are economic units engaged in production for a market. Benefits In Consumption The value of a reduction in risk to an indiv 2 idual is the amount that person would be willing to pay to achieve it. Economic research has not produced a definitive quantitative assessment of willingness to pay for risk reduction in drinking water. 1 Arrow, K.J., “Criteria for Social Investment,” Water Resources Research , Vol. 1, No.1, 1965. 2 Freeman, A.M., The Benefits of Environmental Improvement , Resources for the Future, Washington, D.C., 1979, P. 168. 5—1 ------- Analytical effort has often focused instead on the more tractable problem of computing the value of health-related damages that would be avoided. It is usually assumed that this represents an amount of compensation sufficient to restore an individual whose health has been damaged to their original level of utility. Stated otherwise, the underlying presumption is that, faced with no alternative choices, people would be willing to pay up to the amount of their expected losses in order to avoid those losses. Hence, there is an assumed equivalence between “damages avoided” and “willingness to pay.” This equivalence is incomplete, however, when the valuation of damages is limited to the most readily quantifiable items such as the value of medical costs and lost income. This limited concept of damages ignores the fact that people would not be fully compensated (i.e., not truly indifferent) unless there is also some compensation for the pain, suffering, and inconvenience associated with illness. The presence of these additional damages means there must be a corresponding amount of additional willingness to pay. The additional willingness to pay represents a demand for an additional margin of safety to offset the individual’s fears and anxieties regarding the undesirable consequences of the health risks. It reflects the benefit in consumption provided by the “warranty” --the extra margin of safety -- in public water supplies. Benefits In Production The benefit in production derived from having a margin of safety —— a “warranty” -— in public water supplies consists of the addition to total economic output made possible by the fact that public confidence in the integrity of the water supply facilitates the production and exchange of goods. Without the implied “warranty” in infrastructure systems, the participation of more risk averse individuals in both production and consumption might be limited, constrained, or encumbered by compensating expenditures. Constraints and distortions of this type can result in a lower level of economic output than would otherwise be achievable. The presence of a substantial margin of safety in other categories of infrastructure suggests that the welfare gained by removing such risks as impediments to economic activity significantly outweighs the additional cost. Our expectations of public drinking water supplies are no different from what we expect of other categories of physical infrastructure such as roads, bridges, and buildings. In the design of bridges and buildings, engineers and architects follow a time- honored practice of multiplying their structural calculations by a “safety factor” of two or more. These safety factors are specified in highway construction standards and building codes. Despite the 5—2 ------- fact we have always operated on the presumption that water supplies are safe beyond question, there was no uniform national mechanism for providing a guarantee of the safety of drinking water until the passage of the Safe Drinking Water Act (SDWA) in 1974. The 1986 amendments to the SDWA are intended to complete the process. 5.3 Induced Efficiency Improvements In The Water Industry Water has historically been very abundant, pure (or presumed pure), and inexpensive to produce. In fact, Adam Smith was quite perplexed that something of such obvious value should have such a low price and be taken for granted almost as though it were valueless. This state of relative abundance prevailed from the time of Adam Smith into the early part of the Twentieth Century and our institutions and attitudes have been shaped by it. Even in the arid west, we made water abundant through large federally subsidized water projects. In the absence of compelling cost pressures, there was no need to “economize.” Various non—economic forces have filled the void and evolved as the controlling influences in how we produce, price, and consume water. As a result, many water systems are plagued by a legacy of inadequate maintenance and replacement, and inefficient pricing and capacity management (see expanded discussion of these topics in Chapter 3). Cumulatively, the regulations forthcoming under the 1986 amendments to the Safe Drinking Water Act will have the effect of increasing the per gallon cost of treated water by a sufficient amount that water may no longer be regarded as being inexpensive to produce in many places. The recognition of this new cost environment may induce a variety of efficient improvements in both demand management and supply management in many water systems. The SDWA regulations will increase the incentive for water systems to do a better job of optimizing their maintenance and replacement efforts to fix leaks in distribution systems. The SDWA will provide ihcentive for water systems to adopt more efficient rate structures that encourage more efficient use of capacity. The result of both of these types of improvements is to reduce the treatment capacity requirement. Indirect benefits may also be reaped from improved pricing practices in the area of drought management. The economic costs of shortages are made worse by the inefficiencies of present pricing practices. Environmental costs of inefficient levels of peak period water demands on lakes, groundwater resources, and estuaries are becoming increasingly severe across the country. To the extent that more sophisticated approaches to demand and supply management are encouraged, both economic and environmental benefits will result. Even without rate reforms, higher water rates needed to pay for SDWA improvements will marginally reduce water demands and their resultant 5—3 ------- pressures on the environment. As a final note, the higher water rates needed to pay for SDWA improvements will also induce marginal reductions in waste flows. The benefits derived from induced efficiency improvements may seem, at first blush, to be just a collection of miscellaneous “intangibles.” Lists of miscellaneous items are often of lesser importance. For this reason, the potential importance of the above list must be underscored. This raises three questions that must be addressed. First, how certain is it that the cost pressures of the SDWA program will be sufficient to overcome the inertia of well-entrenched institutional practices and induce the types of efficiency improvements envis- ioned? The answer to this depends on the answer to a second question: how significant will the penalty for inefficiency become in complying with SDWA standards? Answering from the bias of pricing disciplines followed in most other public utilities, it seems likely that when the principles of proper pricing have been so thoroughly ignored, the potential efficiency gains of reform would be large. If the potential gains are large, the penalty for continued inefficiency would be large also. But, this leads to the third question: will the penalty for inefficient practices be recognized, or will it be unknowingly absorbed by water system customers as it has in the past? As the SDWA program is implemented in water systems across the country, the answer to this last question will affect the outcome of every resulting rate increase proposal. Where inefficiencies are allowed to persist, and consumers are unaware of their existence, consumers will not only pay more than they should to achieve SDWA compliance (by the amount of the penalty imposed by the remaining inefficiencies), but will also be given the impression that the entire amount of the rate increase is attributable to SDWA compliance. Disguised in this manner, the inefficiencies will diminish the total reserve of consumer willingness to pay for additional safety in drinking water. This raid on the consumers surplus may ultimately hinder implementation of the SDWA program and result in a lower level of safety than is truly desired. The inefficiencies that have evolved in water system management and water pricing must be recognized if the benefits of safety improvements are to be fairly appreciated. Consumers must be made aware that only a portion of SDWA-induced rate increases relates to safety improvement. The other portion is either a premium required to reverse past inefficiencies or a penalty required to perpetuate them. 5.4 Agc regate Analysis of Health Benefits The calculation of aggregate national level benefits is addressed through assessment of avoidance of direct damages in the 5—4 ------- form of adverse health effects due to a reduction in exposure. As discussed in Chapter 2, exposure to the lOCs evaluated in this document results in various sublethal health effects. Since the EPA has yet to finalize dose/response functions for these sublethal effects, an accurate estimate of the actual number of cases of disease avoided was not possible. Instead, the number of persons that would derive some reduction in exposure to each contaminant as a result of the proposed rule was estimated. In addition to calculation of the reduction in population exposed, an analysis of the potential baseline cancer cases occurring due to asbestos exposure in drinking water was conducted. It should be noted however, that because it is assumed that costs of controlling asbestos are subsumed by other regulations, no benefits are counted for this contaminant in this analysis. Instead, benefits, in the form of a reduction in population exposed, will be quantified in subsequent drafts of the RIAs for the Surface Water Treatment Rule, and the Lead/Corrosion Control Rule. In the process of developing regulatory impact analyses, an assessment of the aggregate benefits is required. Due to the structure of the water supply industry (as outlined in Exhibit 5—1), gross comparisons of national aggregate impacts tend to produce a deceiving picture of the true relationship between costs and benefits at the individual water system level. Aggregate comparisons average together an excess of positive net benefits in large systems with an excess of negative net benefits in small and very small systems. For this reason, aggregate analyses should be viewed only as roughly illustrative of the magnitude of the problem at the national level and caution should be exercised in interpreting these results. A) Sublethal Health Effects Reduction in Population Exposed As suggested above, benefits of removing contamination from drinking water are expressed in terms of cases of disease avoided. To facilitate such calculations, the Agency develops dose/ response relationships or lifetime risk estimates for sub—lethal health effects at chronic, low level exposure whenever possible. However, for the lOCs considered in this analysis, such data were not available. Since all lOCs except asbestos are being regulated on the basis of sublethal health effects, and no usable dose/response data were avai- lable for these contaminants, it was not possible to calculate the number of cases of adverse health effects avoided. For this reason, sublethal health effects benefits associated with the regulation of lOCs in drinking water are presented only in terms of a reduction in the population exposed under the various MCL alternatives. The 3 See Chapter VIII, “Quantification of Toxicological Effects,” in Drinking Water Criteria Document for Inorganic Chemicals (separate document for each contaminant). 5—5 ------- 11 EXHIBIT 5—1 I)i t ii hnt iou of ( oiiiiiiiiiiit y \Va I r Kv - t ( II1H 2.4 23.9 1 0.1 (;.9 I :L3K— 1 OK : i .1 4.fl 10K— I 0 0K , 1001 < Popiti a 11011 i Z( ( a I ego i ie Total f y t( I11 L1 i TI 1 P 1 ). ( FV( d (33.9 70 60 50 In c 1 0 30 20 10 0 25— So o 501 —3.3h. ------- results of these calculations are presented in Exhibits 5-2 and 5- 3 and in Appendix VIII. The net incremental reduction in exposure derived through adoption of the most stringent MCL alternatives would be approx- imately k° 2 million persons in systems serving fewer than 50,000 persons. Excluding the systems estimated to have occurrence of mercury (see Chapter 2 discussion of mercury occurrence estimates), a net reduction of approximately 99 million persons exposed is esti- mated. Benefits of removing cadmium were evaluated at the proposed MCL alternatives. For all other lOCs evaluated, all MCL alterna- tives except the most stringent are either equal to or greater than the existing standard and are therefore assumed to have no net im- pact. The estimated net incremental reduction in exposure derived through adoption of the preferred NCL alternative for cadmium is approximately 170,000 persons in systems serving less than 50,000 persons. B) Baseline Cancer Cases Due to Asbestos Exposure As discussed in Chapter 2, asbestos is being regulated by the Agency as a carcinogen via ingestion exposure. Because it is assumed that asbestos treatment costs will be subsumed by other drinking water regulations, it is most appropriate to attribute any benefits accrued due to asbestos removal to those regulations. To illustrate the probable magnitude of health benefits of controlling asbestos however, an analysis was conducted to estimate the total baseline cancer cases currently attributable to asbestos exposure in drinking water. The results of that analysis are presented below. Estimates of baseline annual cancer cases attributable to asbestos exposure in drinking water were also calculated. Based on the assumption that a concentration of 7.1 million fibers (gre- ater than 10 urn in length) peg liter (MFL) is equal to a io6 individual lifetime cancer risk, the following conversion was made to derive annual individual risk per unit concentration. i x io cases/person/lifetime / 70 years/lifetime 7.1 MFL 2.01 x 10 cases/person/MFL/year 4 At concentrations equivalent to the most stringent MCLs, a significant degree of co-occurrence may be expected. 50 Federal Re ister No. 219, p. 46963. 5—7 ------- EXHIBIT 5—2 REIXrPION 111 P’F’tILATJ(*I ED(F SE1) TO INORGANIC CHEMICALS AT MWT STRIR;ENT MCI ALTERNATIVE (IN THOUSANIS) SYSTE2I SIZE CATIfl4W ’ (RIPIIIATI(t4 SFRVED) MCL : ALL S(IALIY :(W/L) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 SYSTDISSYSTO’IS 25-100 101 -5( 10 5( 11-1K 1K—3 3K 3 3K— bK IOK-25K 25K—SOK SfIK-75K 75k-WOK lOOK-BOOK 500K -3M iN ’ ESTIMATED NUtIDF.R (IF PERSONS EXF(SEI) A&JVE MCGT STRI ICEUI’ MCI. ALTERNATIVE (IN ‘DIOUSAUDS) 3 ‘R irium : ‘. ooo : I 10: 5 thus : s o : 1 Mercury : 2 : 8 Nltiat’/Nitrjte :io,ooo ir . se letiun : 1( 1 : 4 Total Total less Metctir-y 1 1 3 14 14 30 2 5 14 44 90 297 149 158 182 16 25 75 226 293 601 182 2( 13 304 4 4 3 39 38 28 24 30 37 688 847 1,061 192 3( 17 247 159 191 229 1,106 1,417 1,605 418 570 544 1,726 32 2,294 2,573 16. 046 4,933 27,604 25,031 1,959 : 17,541 8,622 0 892 682 3,016 16,181 4.891 3.420 : 18.467 5.763 19.108 : 158,599 76.753 6,611 : 34,580 10.288 34,114 246,26( 1 106.999 ‘30,754 227.793 1( 11.236 (XI11TA?1I tiAlif TOTALS :oaritim : 100 : 160 507 566 1,295 1.993 2,114 1,987 1.156 812 3,266 0 1 18 56 58 122 159 155 114 58 18 102 chrc . iu u s 10 : 30 122 171 525 1.075 1,320 1,648 1,064 1,043 3,813 mer cury : 0 2 : 29 121 201 608 1,310 1,580 1,914 1,225 1,173 4,313 N itrate/N itr ite : 100 : 3,147 6.403 7,006 9,129 17,230 17,261 16,577 9.850 7.483 29,359 :Se lenium : 5 : 33 164 317 1,023 2,334 2,860 3 ,557 2.295 2.244 8,2 ( 19 Total 3,417 7,373 8,319 12,702 24,101 25,290 25,797 15,648 12,773 49,062 Total less Mei-cur-y : 3,388 7,252 8,118 12,094 22,791 23,710 23,883 14,423 11,600 44,749 ESTIMATED NI QIBER OF PERSONS EXF1 ED AI3DVE INTERIM STANDARDS (iN THOUSANDS) 94 86 14 24 686 136 146 1 .007 321 I t S Cachulu urn du n ‘liii :I4er’’u y Nit r ate/fl it t j I c . Se let ii UI T o In] :Tot a1 t.’ s (ler’uiy (I 3 5 25 24 87 674 2.463 74 324 139 5 1 1 916 3.413 242 950 159 13 29 21 3,072 2 ) 3,323 3,30” ESTIMATED 1111’ RELUCFION IN TI-fE NIJI-IBER OF PERSONS EXF GE1) AT M(6T STI ?IIflFNT MCI ALTERNATIVE (IN ‘IlI(*JSANLS) 1 0 8 52 71 1,483 1,991 151 136 3(14 402 1,999 2.600 516 609 22 220 371 1 1 )332 2,131 2, 2 (11 15,277 4,945 506 565 1,292 42 44 92 120 166 511 77 111 311 6.254 6.848 8,947 148 292 948 1.147 8,026 12,101 7,070 7,915 11,790 1,989 120 1,051 622 17,038 2.175 22.995 22,373 2.110 1,984 117 86 1,290 1,611 733 853 16,954 16,330 2.669 3.328 23,873 24.192 23,141 1 23.339 I . 155 44 1 ,(4(I 539 9,714 2.149 14.641 14, 102 812 13 1,019 499 7.4( 19 2, m c 11.857 11.150 17 168 113 3,035 1.310 699 5,342 2,307 8 .605 514 4,778 2 .728 75 .443 9 .589 101,657 90.929 I u nits cc-4nimu1 Ly triter systtru. iii ion-transient, non-conmisity waLer cy t.cm’, for all cc’rtami,anL5 E’Vct pL rIt rnt’/ni t i -i t o For I I . ‘ , nrutaniraxrt.w a El pub ] Ic water systems are in’ I i f r i 2 Sn-uI 1 .y’it’ m arc tti’-’s C’ rv I us “II, (10( 1 ;ei soot, or fewer 3 A l II’’ ne , l ‘-ti urigeuui 1*1. all-rI iv .- ., thore urO y Ix) sigulfic—nit co—’e’a ic’nn of l i 5 3,263 77 3,726 1,85(1 29,( ’35 7,690 45,649 ‘13,799 I .725 24 2,242 I ,(190 15,895 4.629 25,605 :4,515 1,959 : 17,519 a: 672 3.005 : 15.810 1,429 : 8.135 18.972 : 456,468 6,209 : 32,379 31,574 : 230,983 30.145 : 222,848 ------- EXIIIBrT 5—3 RFJACTJC*4 IN FOFIJLATICtI EXF(SED TO !t&WGAHIC CIIE?IICALS AT PREFERRED t EL ALTERNATIVE (IN Th($JSANDS) I I SXSTE]1 SIZE CATWORY TOTALS (POF IJLATIC 4I SERVED) 2 ONTANItJANT HCt : ALL StALL ( ( lU/L) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 SYSTE IIS SYSTE IIS 25-1(0 101—5(0 501-1K 1K—3 3K 3 3K— bK 10K-25K 25K—50K 50K-75K 75k-lOOK 100K-bOOK SOOK—IM 111-. ESTIMATED MEMBER OF PEESCES EXREED ABOVE PRCflEEI) IICL ALTERNATIVES (IN ThC*JSANL$) :cadmiiun 5 9 28 29 61 80 76 57 29 9 51 16 0 445 340: • — I I I ESTIMATED NUMBER OF PERS(*4S FIRGEI) ABOVE INTERIM SFANDAALG (IN T HCIOSANIX) :Cadm lum : 1( 1; 5 14 14 30 39 38 28 14 5 25 8 0 220 168 I I I I ESTIMATED NET Rk]XKJTIC*l IN THE NUMBER OF PERSC*45 EXF(SE]) AT PROFUSE!) MCL ALTERNATIVES (IN 1 1IC AISANIS) lID :Uadm lum 4 14 15 31 41 38 29 15 4 26 8 0 225 172 • I I — —I 1 Includes cccriunity water systems and non-transient, non-coon*nlty water systems 2 Sanl 1 systems are those servIng 50 .0(10 ( rsons or fewer ------- The EPA has prepared draft estimates of the populati 6 on exposed to various levels of asbestos in community water systems and these served as the basis for estimates of baseline cancer cases. Exhibit 5-4 summarizes estimates of the total population exposed to various concentrations of asbestos in CWS. EXHIBIT 5-4 Estimated Population Exposed (Millions) to Various Concentrations of Asbestos in Community Drinking Water Systems > 7.1 MFL > 0.71 MFL > 0.071 MFL 0 — 0.071 MFL LOW 0.73 7.1 16.0 199.0 HI 1.2 7.5 20.0 203.0 No data were available regarding average asbestos concentra- tions in affected systems. Therefore, to facilitate calculation of baseline cases, it was necessary to make assumptions regarding the concentrations to which the various segments of the population are exposed. For the population exposed above 7.1 MFL), estimates were ca1cu1 ted using average concentrations ranging between 7.5 and 70 MFL. For the segment of the population exposed to levels below 7.1 MFL but above 0.071 MFL, a low scenario assuming average influent concentrations equal to the geometric mean of the range (e.g., for the population exposed between 0.071 MFL and 0.71 MFL the average concentration was assumed to be 0.22 MFL). A corresponding high scenario assumed maximum average concentrations within each range (e.g., for the population exposed between 0.071 MFL and 0.71 MFL the average was assumed to be 0.70 MFL). Finally, for the remainder of the population (i.e., those exposed to less than 0.071 MFL), an average concentration of 0.355 MFL was assumed for the low exposure scenario (i.e., one-half the 6 Science Applications International Corporation, 1986, Estimated National Occurrence and Exposure to Asbestos in Public Drinking Water Supplies . December 23 draft. It should be noted that occurrence analyses for asbestos were conducted under the assumption that the proposed MCL would be 7.1 MFL. As such, estimates of systems affected and populations exposed may represent a slight underestimate from that expected at 7 MFL. 7 me occurrence data indicate that there is no exposure above 71 MFL. 5—10 ------- minimum reporting level), and a concentration of 0.07 MFL was assumed for the high scenario. Under all exposure scenarios evaluated, the annual baseline cases of cancer were estimat ed to be 0.3 or less, using the annual risk factor described above. Due to the small baseline estimates, and the error inherent in those estimates, it was not considered meaningful to calculate cases of cancer avoided and consequently no further analysis was performed for asbestos. The full range of baseline cancer cases under all exposure scenarios is presented in Exhibit 5—5 below. 8 1t should be noted that it was not possible to discern the proportion of exposure attributable to large water systems from these data. However, because the vast majority of asbestos occurrence is though to result from corrosion of asbestos/cement (A/C) pipe (see Chapter 2), and because many large water systems have exten- sive amounts of A/C pipe in their distribution systems, it may be inappropriate to “assume away” the exposure in large systems as was done for arsenic. 5—11 ------- EXHIBIT 5—5 Estimated Baseline Cancer Cases Due to Asbestos Contamination in Community Drinking Water Systems Assumed Avg. Concentration Estimated Assumed Average Concentration for for population Number of Populations Exposed Above 7.1 MFL Exposed B low Persons 7.1 MFL 1 ’ Exposed 3 7.5 MFL 15 MFL 30 MFL 70 MFL LOW LOW 0.06 0.07 0.09 0.15 HI 0.07 0.08 0.12 0.22 HI LOW 0.14 0.15 0.17 0.23 HI 0.15 0.17 0.21 0.30 1 NFL - Million intermediate length (> 10 urn) fibers per length. 2 Assumptions regarding average concentrations for segments of the population exposed below 7.1 MFL range from 0.0355 NFL to 2.25 MFL under the low scenario, and from 0.07 MFL to 7.00 MFL under the high scenario. The number of persons exposed at various concentration levels could not be estimated precisely in EPA’s occurrence analysis. As a result, the estimates are presented as a range. It is estimated that between 16 million and 20 million persons are exposed to asbestos at concentrations exceeding 0.071 MFL, and of these, between 0.73 and 1.2 million are exposed above 7.1 MFL (see Exhibit 5—4). 5—12 ------- 6. REGULATORY FLEXIBILITY ANALYSIS AND PAPERWORK REDUCTION ANALYSIS 6.1 Requlatory Flexibility Analysis The Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA), enacted on September 19, 1980, requires all executive agencies to explicitly consider small entities in their regulatory design and implementation pro- cess. The purpose of the RFA is to encourage regulatory agencies to minimize any disproportionate burden that falls on small enti- ties. The specific objectives of the RFA are: o To increase agenciest awareness of their regulatory impact on small entities; o To compel agencies to explicitly analyze, explain, and publish regulatory impacts on small entities; and o To encourage agencies to provide regulatory relief to small entities while still accomplishing their statutory mandates. These objectives are accomplished through the reqi.lireinents of regulatory flexibility analyses for proposed regulations. If a regulation does not have a “significant” impact on a “substantial” number of small entities, then the regulatory flexibility analysis will consist of a certification to that effect. Prior to conducting a regulatory flexibility an lysis, a regulatory agency such as EPA must define a small entity. The RFA defines small entities a including small businesses, organ- izations, and governments.’ A small business is defined as “any business which is independently owned and operated and not dominant in its field.” 3 A small organization is defined as “any non—profit enterprise which is independently owned and operated and is not dominant in its field.” Finally, small government entities are defined as “those city, county, town, township, village, school district, or special district governments serving a population of less than 50,000 persons.” 1 1t should be noted that under the SDWA EPA’s Office of Drinking Water employs a different definition of a “small entity” for small water systems. The analyses presented in this section are prepared only for compliance with the RFA. 2 Regulatory Flexibility Act of 1980, PL 96—354, Section 601(6) USC, Section 632. 4 op. cit. , note # 2 supra , Sections 601(4) and 601(5). 6—1 ------- community water systems can be divided into three ownership categories for the purpose of RFA analysis: 1) publicly owned; 2) investor owned; and, 3) ancillary systems. Publicly owned systems are those owned by governmental entities; investor owned systems are privately owned; and ancillary systems are those small systems that are ancillary to other enterprises such as mobile home parks or hospitals. According to EPA, there are 26,424 publicly owned community water systems. 5 Of this total, 98 percent serve fewer than 50,000 persons. Investor owned water systems are firms prima ily engaged in production and distribution of water to consumers. According to regulations published in accordance with the RFA, these companies are considered to be sma .1 businesses if their annual receipts are less than $3.5 million. To apply this standard to public water systems, the Consumer Price Index for other utilities and public services was used to normalize operating costs from 1984 to 1986 dollars. This procedure suggests that the upper limit for a small water utility would be $3.8 million per year in 1986 dollars. The EPA estimates that systems serving populations of 50,000 persons generate revenues of approximately $3.8 million. 8 Revenues for investor owned water systems serving 25,000 to 50,000 persons averaged $3.5 million in 1986. For investor owned systems serving 50,000 to 75,000 persons, revenues in 1986 averaged approximately $5.2 million. Therefore, public systems serving 50,000 persons or fewer will be considered “small entities” for purposes of this regulatory flexibility analysis. There is some question, however, as to whether all investor owned water utilities serving fewer than 50,000 persons qualify as small businesses. Many of these utilities are not individually owned, but are owned and controlled by large holding companies such as American Water Works Service Co. and General Water Works. In addition, every investor owned utility operates in a franchised area and thus constitutes a monopoly. This raises the question of whether domination in a limited geographic area is the same as dominance in a field of enterprise. The Small Business Administration considers dominance to mean on a national basis: therefore, no individual water utility can be dominant in the marketplace. Most ancillary community water systems serve fewer than 3,300 persons (10 ancillary systems serve populations between 3,300 and 25,000). These could be considered small entities; however, the main activity of the enterprise may be sufficiently large to 5 u.s. Environmental Protection Agency - Office of Drinking Water. Survey of Community Water Systems . October, 1987. 4941. 749 Federal Register , No. 28, p. 5035, 1984. 8 o .cit., note # 5 supra , p. 42. 6—2 ------- disqualify some organizations as small entities. Howeve , at least 73 percent of ancillary systems are mobile home parks; it seems unlikely that other revenue sources at these facilities would be sufficient to offset the burden of regulations significantly. Nevertheless, it is not possible to determine precisely how many ancillary systems constitute small entities due to the lack of data. Purpose of the Requlation The purpose of this regulation is to reduce public health risks by limiting human exposure to inorganic chemical contaminants in drinking water, and to comply with the provisions of the SDWA Amendments. The SDWA authorizes EPA to set maximum contaminant levels (MCLs) for those contaminants in drinking water having any adverse effect on the health of persons. If the Administrator finds that it is not technologically or economically feasible to regulate contamination to a specific level, a treatment technique requirement may be promulgated in lieu of establishing an MCL. Moreover, the SDWA Amendments mandate that “. . .the Administrator shall publish maximum contaminant level goals and national imary drinking water regulations [ for 83 specific contaminantsJ.” The inorganic chemicals evaluated in this document are included in that list of 83 contaminants. Number of Small Entities Affected Because of the health risks associated with inorganic contain- inants, the nature of their occurrence in public water supplies, and the generally limited treatment currently in place, the revised standards for these contaminants are likely to affect small water systems. EPA guidance on compliance with the RFA indicate that, in general, a “substantial” number of small entities is more than 20 percent of the total. Of the estimated 199,390 public water supplies serving fewer than 50,000 persons, 333 (0.2 percent) will incur treatment and waste disposal costs under the revised bC regulations (assuming an MCL equivalent to the MCLG). Therefore, by the 20 percent rule, the proposed ICC regulations would not affect a “substantial” number of small water utilities at the preferred MCL alternatives. The incremental number of systems affected for each contaminant is shown in Exhibit 6-1. 9 op_cit., note #5 supra , p. 9. 10 Safe Drinking Water Act Amendments of 1986, P.L. 99—339, Section 1412 (b) (1) 6—3 ------- EXHIBIT 6—1 Estimated Number of Small Entities Affected by Proposed bC Rule # of Small # of Small Net Number Systems Systems of Small Percent Affected at Affected at Systems of Small Preferred MCL Interim Std. Affected Systems Barium 0 19 0 0 Cadmium 380 188 192 0.1 Chromium 0 20 0 0 Mercury 0 0 0 0 Nitrate 917 917 0 0 Nitrite 0 0 0 0 Selenium 0 185 0 0 TOTAL 192 0.1 Economic Impacts on Small Entities Under the RFA, annual costs of compliance are to be compared to the existing cost of production. This comparison may not be applicable for water supply since it is not clear what comprises the cost of production in this industry. The cost of production is reflected in the price of the product in most industries, but as discussed in Chapter 3, pricing practices in the water industry are highly variable and not necessarily reflective of the full cost of production. Therefore, data from the 1986 Survey of Community Water Systems on water utility operating expenses were used as a proxy for cost of production. According to the 1986 survey, the total annual operating expense for small systems was approximately $14.7 billion. The total annualized treatment and waste disposal costs for removal of lOCs in affected systems serving fewer than 50,000 persons (using the market discount rate of 10 percent) are approximately $14.6 million. As detailed in Chapter 4, the total uncertainty associated with this estimate is between 20 and 28 percent, depending on the assumptions used regarding the correla- tion of standard errors. Using 28 percent as an upper bound, annualized incremental treatment and waste disposal costs for lOCs may range from $6.8 to $22.4 million, with 95 percent confidence. To examine the incremental impacts on small systems two alternative methods were used. The first method, a macro-level analysis, calculates aggregate incremental costs as a percent of aggregate cost of production (operating expense) for all small systems including both those systems affected and those not 6—4 ------- affected by the rule. Exhibit 6-2 shows the total cost impact to range from 0.05 to 0.15 percent using the macro-level analysis. EXHIBIT 6—2 Production Cost Increase (Macro—Level Analysis) Total Cost Increase Percent Increase ( S Millions) in Production Cost Lower Bound 6.8 0.05 Best Estimate 14.6 0.10 Upper Bound 22.4 0.15 The second method for calculating incremental cost impacts, a micro-level analysis, examines the impact on those systems within each size category that will incur remediation costs under the rule. The 1986 survey reports an average operating expense for private systems serving fewer than 50,000 persons of $2.27 per one thousand gallons. Using data from the same survey on the average daily flows produced by systems of various sizes, the annual cost figures cited above can be converted to a cents-per-thousand gallons basis. This reflects the incremental additional cost of production for individual systems. Exhibit 6-3 compares these amounts to the present level of production costs. Agency guidance regarding the RFA defines a percentage increase in production cost of five percent or more as a signif i- cant impact. The macro-level analysis indicates that the Inorgan- ic Chemical Regulation would not exceed this threshold; however, when examined at the micro-level it is very likely that the ICC Rule exceeds this threshold according to the data shown in Exhibit 6—3. RFA guid 1ines also call for an analysis of whether the com- pliance costs as a percentage of sales for small entities are 10 percent or more higher than compliance costs as a percentage of sales for large entities. There are two inherent features of the water industry that would make such an analysis misleading. In community water systems, the economies of scale are such that virtually any SDWA compliance action that is undertaken in a small entity is bound to cost more than 10 percent as much as it would cost in a large water system. Thus, the analysis would not be very informative. With respect to non—community water systems, water supply is often an ancillary activity undertaken in the course of providing some other primary business service. For example, non-community 6—5 ------- water systems may be ski lodges, roadside restaurants, campgrounds, and the like. The data on non-community water systems is not adequate to perform an assessment of how many of them are engaged in each of these different business activities. Thus, it is impos- sible to analyze the impact in terms of the percentage increase in costs as a percentage of sales. E fIBIT 6-3 Production Cost Increase by System Size Category (Micro-Level Analysis) System Incremental Percentage Size Production Cost Increase in Category ( Cents/l000 Gal.) Production Cost 25 — 100 571 206 101 — 500 286 111 501 — 1,000 151 92 1,001 — 3,300 97 59 3,301 — 10K 78 56 10,001 — 25K 61 44 25,001 — 50K 52 63 All Size Categories: High Bound 586 224 Best Estimate 381 146 Low Bound 176 66 RFA guidelines further require an analysis of the extent to which capital costs of compliance represent a significant portion of capital available to small entities and whether the requirements of the regulation are likely to result in closures of small entities. While it seems certain that some small entities will encounter financial problems in achieving compliance, the data with which to estimate the extent of such problems does not exist. The SDWA has explicit exemption procedures, however, specifically designed to accommodate the financial problems of small water systems. The SDWA incorporates mechanisms for states to mitigate economic impacts on small systems. At least for some systems in the smallest size categories (i.e., less than 150 service connec- tions), the most important mechanism may be the authority to exempt systems from regulatory requirements on economic grounds while alternative means of compliance are sought. 6—6 ------- 6.2 Paperwork Reduction Analysis Paperwork Reduction Act Among the purposes of the Paperwork Reduction Act (PRA) 11 are as follows: o minimization of the federal paperwork burden for indivi- duals, small businesses, state and local governments, and other persons; and, o minimization of the costs to the federal government of collecting, maintaining, using, and disseminating infor- mation. Water utilities and state water supply agencies will be required to maintain records on monitoring for lOCs and report results to the EPA; this is likely to be the largest component of paperwork associated with establishment of Federal bC regulations. The Paperwork Reduction Act is intended to minimize the burden imposed on utilities and states as they strive to protect the public health by implementing the provisions of the SDWA. Requirements of the Paperwork Reduction Act EPA is required to submit to the Office of Management and Budget COMB) proposed information collection requests. EPA also must submit a copy of proposed rules containing an information collection requirement. These proposed rules must be submitted no later than publication of a notice of proposed rulemaking in the Federal Register. When a final rule is published in the Federal Register, EPA must explain how any information collection requirements have been designed to be responsive to public com- ments. 0MB determines the necessity, practicality, and utility of the information being requested, and if approval of the request is made, 0MB will issue a control order. Under the Safe Drinking Water Act, EPA is authorized to regulate contaminants in drinking water to protect the public health. Inorganic contaminants are known to constitute a health risk. To determine whether a specific water system exceeds an MCL for bOCs, EPA must require water systems to collect arid analyze samples and report results to the relevant primacy agent (i.e., either the applicable EPA regional office or the states). In the case of inorganic contaminants, EPA, the states, water utilities, and the public would use monitoring information for two purposes: 1) to determine the presence of contaminants which may affect human health; and 2) to determine the reliability of a system to provide waters free of inorganic contaminants. This monitoring data would also allow appropriate action plans and removal decisions to be made by affected utilities. 11 Public Law 96—511; 94 STAT 2812 6—7 ------- Number of Systems Affected/Respondent Burden A detailed discussion of the nuin.ber of water systems affected by monitoring and paperwork requirements associated with the proposed rules is provided in the Information Collection Request Documents. 6—8 ------- 7. SUMMARY OF COSTS, BENEFITS, AND UNCERTAINTY This chapter summarizes the aggregate impacts estimated to result from the proposed revisions to drinking water regulations for lOCs. Due to the structure of the water supply industry (as outlined in Exhibit 5-1), such gross comparisons of aggregate impacts produce a deceiving picture of the true relationship between costs and benefits at the system level. Aggregate com- parisons average together an excess of positivebenefjts in larger systems with an excess of negative benefits in small and very small systems. For this reason, aggregate analyses should be viewed only as roughly illustrative of the magnitude of the problem at the national level. 7.1 Total Incremental National Costs Total incremental national costs of proposed IOC regulations are summarized in Exhibits 7-1 and 7-2 at the most stringent MCL alternatives and the proposed MCL alternatives, respectively. Total national costs include treatment, waste disposal, monitoring, and impacts on state regulatory programs associated with implementation. Exhibit 7—1 shows that regulating all lOCs at the most stringent MCL alternatives may affect as many as 115,800 water systems, excluding projected mercury occurrence. Total incremental capital costs of this regulatory alternative would be approximately $41 billion. Annualized costs for treatment and waste disposal, which would include both amortized capital and annual expenditures for O&M, would be between $7.3 and $8.4 billion, depending on the discount rate applied. Incremental monitoring costs would be an additional $4 million per year. At the most stringent MCL alternatives, incremental impacts would result for all contaminants because the standards would be lowered from their current levels and many additional water systems would be affected. However, these estimates may represent an over- estimation of impacts due to co-occurrence of lOCs at such low concentrations, and the simultaneous removal of multiple con- taminants which would generally occur during treatment. Exhibit 7-2 shows incremental impacts of regulations at the preferred MCL alternatives. For barium, chromium, mercury, ni- trate, and selenium, the revised standards would be equal to or greater than the existing standards and therefore no incremental impacts for treatment, waste disposal or exposure reduction would be attributable to the rule for these substances. Also, it is assumed that the costs associated with treatment to address as- bestos contamination would be subsumed as systems complied with the lead and surface water treatment rules. Finally, it is assumed 7—1 ------- EXHIBIT 7-1 Estimated Impact of Regulating lOCs at Most Stringent MCL Alternatives 1 ’ 2 ’ 3 Contaminant I Benefits, IMonitoring’t treatment Costs Mutter of Kecbct;on in I Sysieme Poçaaiation Arraial Capital 0tH tug/I) I Affected I Eaposed I t aijyr) (S m l (S m/yr) Waste Costs Capital DIM c i a) tS 0/yr) Total Costs I Aswajalized Costs ft yr) Capital DIM I tie) (Salyi) a3x ass a x Estimated tepacta at Host Stringent MCIs tat imated lepaci of Current MCLI Promulgated Under MiPOsis 19 16,800 I 188 168,711 I 20 111,884 I 3,034,994 2,527 I 1,309,354 I 185 I 699,122 I 5,340,865 I 2,939 2,305,871 I I S i 5 0 I 59 4 I 31 2 I 19 2 8 I I 553 62 99 ‘ I I 469 67 I 26.4 12 I I 45 5 I 3 0 2.0 I 1,130 141 I 410 24 I sAl 577 311 15 I 10 1 70 6I 27 652 71 I 735 48 s 1.540 165 888 94, Estimated Met incremental lepacts at Host sir ingent i4CLs water systems serving less than 50,000 people for alt contaminants include alt public water supplies serving fewer than 50,000 people. over 20 years. Bariin Catiiaa I Chrmeii,n Mercury Mliraie/Mltrlte I Selenii.as iota! Total teas Mercury I°° Oi l 10 I 02 I 100 SI 6,7 13 I 760 I 1,323 1,378 I 108,227 p 1,713 I 8 .621 ,581 I 682,525 4,821,091 I 5 ,763,242 I 76,753,205 I 10,287,008 p 2,090 196 I 765 1,206 22,335 p 409 —2 206 I 18 I 78 I 137 3,456 I 120,114 p 106,998,652 118,736 p 101,225,410 2,032 127 572 234 12,536 672 6 1 27,001 3,942 I 16,173 BA 25,795 3,805 I 15 ,939 137 4,122 343 7 I 323 251 46 1,337 124 I 18 1,440 155 60 1 34,871 4,057 42 I 1,081 891 851 41,174 4,793 833 I 4i,734 4,638 Mama 1,000 Ca kaa 10 Chromlias 50 Mercury 2 I I Nitrate/Nitr Ite 10,000 teieni.n 10 p iota! Total teas Mercury Bar ia n I Cadaitsa I Chromiaaa Mercury I Miiraie/ itriie Salenti.aa total total less Mercury I 6,694 p I 572 1 I i,303 I I 933 I 105,700 I 1,528 8,604,781 I 511,814 I 4,779,207 I 2,728,248 75,441,85 1 I 9,587,886 p I iS? 14 I 96 746 76 I 564 I 655 75 135 I 21,866 3,389 p 12,2 72 366 42 116,750 101,657,78 7 p p 1 15 ,79? p 98,929,539 I 4 1 25 ,871 3,801 15 ,763 a x 25,218 3,726 I 15,628 137 I 4,112 342 I 253 19 1 I 1,310 i I 788 841 589 I 34,158 3,978 42 I 1,033 84 I 827 41,654 4.628 I 818 40,846 4,544 1 Includes Cofrninity and non-transient non-coimsinity except Nitrate/Nitrite. Nitrate/Nitrite estimates 2 Costs expressed in 1986 Dot tars and are annualized 618 36 209 137 6,273 153 7,426 7,289 672 7301 39- 226 245 I 147 158 I 6,717 7,200 p 167 182 7,969 8,558 7,822 8,400 3 At most stringent MCI alternatives there may be significant co-occurrence of lOCs. 4 Routine cotrpliance monitoring costs include estimates for all contaminants; in addition, monitoring for unregulated contaminants is estimated to result in a one time cost of $0.2 million. ------- EXHIBIT 7-2 Estimated Impact of Regulating lOCs at Proposed MCL Alternatives I I 4 Benefits: IMonitorin?I Treatment Costs Waste Costs 4 Total Costs 4 lAnnuatized Costs (S m/yr) I Number oflReduction liii I I I I I MCI Systems Population Annual I Capital 0&M Capital O&M Capital O&M I Contaminant 1 (ug/l) I Affected I Exposed (S m/yr) (S m) (S m/yr) (S m) (S m/yr) I (S m) (S m/yr) a 3% a sz a 7% Estimated Impact of Proposed MCI5 Cadmium 5 I 380 I 341,125 4.1 79 8 64 4 143 12 - - - - - - I I I Estimated Impact of Current MCL5 Promulgated Under NIPDWR Ca d mium 10 168,711 2.0 3 9 4 I 31 2 I 70 6 I - - - - - - Estimated Net Incremental Impacts of Proposed MCI5 Cadmium I 192 I 172,414 I 2.1 I 40 4 I 33 2 I 73 6 I 11 12 13 I I I 1 The preferred MCL5 for barium, chromium, mercury, nitrate, and selenium are greater than or equal to the interim MCI5, hence the incremental impacts of removing these contaminants are assisiied to be zero. Nitrite occurrence is assumed to be negtigible, therefore no benefits or treatment and waste disposal costs would be incurred for this contaminant Benefits and treatment and waste disposal costs for asbestos are subsumed by other drinking water regulations. 2 Include coomunity and non-transient non-coeininity water systems serving Less than 50,000 people. 3 Routine coepliance monitoring costs include estimates for all contaminants; in addition, monitoring for unregulated contaminants is estimated to result in a one time cost of $0.2 million. 4 Costs are expressed in 1986 Dollars and are annualized over 20 years ------- that nitrite occurrence is negligible and that no treatment or waste disposal costs would be incurred under the proposal. It is estimated that 192 water systems will incur treatment costs for cadmium. Capital costs associated with the preferred MCL alternatives are $73 million and the total annualized treatment and waste disposal costs will amount to $11 to $13 million depending on the discount rate applied. Monitoring costs will be approximately $2 million per year. An estimate of the total costs to state programs for the entire Phase II regulatory package (i.e., including both lOCs and synthetic organic chemicals) is included in the draft Regulatory Impact Analysis for Synthetic Organic Chemicals. 7.2 Total Incremental National Benefits Incremental national benefits at the most stringent MCL alternatives and at the preferred MCL alternatives are summarized in Exhibits 7-1 and 7—2, respectively. Due to the lack of dose/response data for sub—lethal health effects, it was necessary to present aggregate benefits estimates for non-carcinogens as a reduction in population exposed. At the most stringent MCL alternatives, it is estimated that approximat- ely 102 million persons may be provided such a reduction in exposure. This may over—estimate the true reduction in exposure, however, due to the probability of co-occurrence at these concen- trations. At the proposed MCL alternatives, the total incremental benefits will include a reduction in exposure to lOCs of approx- imately 170,000 persons, and avoidance of six cases of cancer per year due to arsenic exposure. 1 While treatment and waste disposal costs will be borne only by systems which violate the standard for arsenic or cadmium, monitoring costs will be borne by all systems, and include costs for all contaminants in the proposed rule. 7—4 ------- |