COST SHARING WITH INDUSTRY? Summary Report of the Working Committee on Economic Incentives (Revised) The Working Committee is one of several Committees under the direction of The Federal Coordinating Committee on the Economic. Impact of Pollution Abatement November 20, .1967 Room 325 Executive Office Building 395-5080 or Code 103-5080 ------- CONTENTS Page Introduction \ Summary i Recommendations 4 Present Federal Assistance 6 General Assistance 6 Water Pollution Abatement Assistance 6 Air Pollution Abatement .Assistance 9 Current Costs of Pollution Control for Manufacturing Firms . 12 Quest for Better Data 12 Likely Additional Abatement Costs 14 Additional Costs of WateT Pollution Control 14 An Alternative Estimate of the Additional Cost of Water Pollution Control ^ The Additional Cost of Air Pollution Control 19 An Alternative Partial Cost Estimate: Twenty City Model of Electric Power Plants 23 Possible Additional Federal Subsidies 26 Tax Writeoffs . 26 Grants and Loans for Industry 29 Assistance Based on Hardship 29 Assistance Based on Burden 33 Performance Grants 34 The User Charge and the Effluent or Emission Charge . 34 Summary 36 Members of the Working Committee on Economic Incentives . 37 ------- TABLES Page Table I Federal Water Pollution Control Grant & Enforcement Budget (FY 1968 Estimate) 7 Table II Federal Air Pollution Expenditures (FY 1968 Estimate ) 10 Table III State and Local Expenditure for Air Pollution Control (FY 1967} 11 Table IV Estimate of Replacement Cost, Annual Cost, and Burden of Water Waste Treatment Facilities for 13 Manufacturing in 1966 Table V Estimate of Additional Annual Cost of Water Pollution Abatement to Meet a Hypothetical Industrial Standard Requiring 85% Removal of Biochemical Oxygen Demanding Wastes and Suspended Solids 16 Table VI Comparison of Waste Treatment Required h. Distribution of Value of Manufacturing Output Assuming Hypothetical Waste Treatment of 85% of Biochemical Oxygen Demanding Wastes and Suspended Solids, 1966 18 Table VII Additional Annual Cost to Achieve the Water Quality Standard Established for the Delaware River Estuary and an Extrapolation for All Manufacturing Firms Based on Waste Water Discharged by Manufacturers in the Estuary and the Country, 1966 20 Table VIII Annual Cost of Achieving a Hypothetical Standard by Reducing Human Exposure of Sulphur Oxides and Particulates by 60 to 75% in a "Typical City" of 2 Million People and Extrapolated for the United States, 1967 22 Table IX Affected Fuel and Hypothesized Cost of Achieving Fuel Standards for Electric Power Generation Plants located in or near the Twenty Cities with the Worst Sulphur Oxide Problems, 1967 25 Table X Comparison of the Additional Subsidy to Industry 28 Through Alternative Forms of Federal Assistance Table XI Number and Proportion of All Manufacturing Firms Potentially Eligible to be Considered for Pollution Abatement Assistance under Programs of the Small Business Administration 31 ------- INTRODUCTION This report summarizes the Working Committee's evaluation of the advisability of further assistance for industry and possible alternative approaches for such assistance. The Working Committee on Industrial Incentives is part of a larger effort to look at the economic impact of pollution abatement as directed by the President. JJ The report is divided into six parts: (1) Summary; (2) Recom- mendations; (3) Magnitude and nature of present Federal assistance to industry; (4) Summary of the expenditures currently made by industry; (5) Estimates of costs for air aftd ^'ater abatements; and (6) Analysis of several proposed Federal subsidies. SUMMARY The average additional annual cost caused by higher levels of pollution abatement are estimated to be significant but relatively small for all manufacturing firms. Moreover, Federal assistance to industry is already sizeable and is growing especially in the area of R&D intended to lower abatement costs. Therefore the need and desirability of additional assistance for industry should be judged on the basis of hardship or burden on particular industries, firms or plants (or hardship on particular communities) caused by abatement actions rather than on the burden to industry as a whole. Present Federal Assistance The Federal Government offers general assistance to industry in the form of the 7% investment tax credit for capital equipment including pollution abatement equipment. The overall Federal water pollution program, in the excess of $400 million annually, is helpful, to industry as well as States, municipalities, and interstate agencies. 1/ Development of analysis was assigned to Interior, Health, Education, & Welfare and the Council of Economic Advisers. At the request of all parties to the evaluation effort, a coordinating committee on the economic impact of pollution abatement was established last summer. All Federal agencies having responsibility in the area of pollution abatement are represented on Federal committee: Agriculture, Atomic Energy Commission, Bureau of the Budget, Council of Economic Advisers, Commerce, Corps of Engineers, Federal Power Commission, Health, Education 81 Welfare, Interior,Labor, Office of Emergency Planning, Office of Science and Technology, State, Treasury, and the Water Resources Council. The Working Committee on Economic Incentives is one of several committees under the coordinating committee and is composed of representatives from BOB, CEA, Commerce, HEW', Interior, OS/T, Treasury and the Water Resources Council. ------- -2- Elements of this program include research and development, training, and planning grants and municipal construction grants. Manufacturing firms benefit from municipal facilities which receive Federal grants as well as gaining benefits from economies-of-scale. For air, Federal assistance is estimated to be over $100 million in FY 1968 and is scheduled to increase markedly under the provisions of the Clean Air Act of 1967. These funds are now spent for research and development, demonstration grants, training and data collection. While Federal assistance is already sizeable, it is reasonable to believe that additional research and development funds, if directed towards bottleneck problems, are likely to be highly productive in reducing the cost of abatement. Moreover, this is a desirable and appropriate way for government to assist industry. Additional Cost qf Abatement The additional annual cost for water pollution abatement (secondary treatment) by manufacturing plants is estimated to be approximately $1/4 billion. This is equivalents© . 13% of total value-added by manu- facturing firms in 1966. The additional cash flow occasioned by the require- ment to meet the hypothetical standard of secondary treatment (85% level) within 5 years could cause the demand for pollution abatement funds to nearly double to approximately $1/2 billion oirl/4% of value-added by manufacturing. The annual cash flow requirement would correspondingly be less during the succeeding years unless standards were raised higher. Roughly one-fifth of additional treatment cost borne by manu- facturing firms was estimated to occur through using municipal facilities. The cost of control could be much greater if high environmental quality standards are set. Or the cost of control would likely be less if locational factors, special purpose water basins and cheaper production- process changes are considered -- as they will likely be considered in practice. Some manufacturing industries, firms and plants will face costs which will vary considerably from the average. For example, the chemical industry is likely to face abatement costs nearly four times above the average or . 5% of value-added while electrical machinery can anticipate costs which are one-fourth of the average or approximately . 04% of value-added. ------- -3- The additional costs of air pollution abatement are more uncertain than for water. However, the additional annual cost in the case of a 60% to 75% reduction of human exposure to sulphur oxides and particulate pollutants in all Standard Metropolitan Statistical Areas is estimated to be about $3/4 billion. Roughly 46% Of $354 million of this cost may- be borne by manufacturing firms and electric power companies; therefore, the additional burden should total approximately 0.16% of value-added in 1966. The additional annual burden for other waste load emitters -- primarily space heating of residences, apartments and non-manufacturing businesses --is estimated to be $415 million or $2. 96 per capita, which is 0.11% of per capita income. The cost can easily double or quadruple if abatement is required for all waste load emissions rather than limiting abatement to harmful discharges only. This is particularly true with electric power generation plants which are heavy emitters of SO^ but are not necessarily heavy polluters. The additional annual costt for manufacturing firms and electric power plants (excluding thermal pollution abatement) to achieve the hypo- thetical quality standards considered in this report far^hoth air and water is estimated to be approximately $1 billion or less than 1/3% of value-added for manufacturing and the electric power industries. Proposals for Assistance Various proposals for additional assistance to industry beyond obvious improvements or expansion of existing Federal programs were evaluated as follows. Across-the-board assistance for capital investment such as tax writeoffs (credits or accelerated depreciation) and grants are unnecessary because the burden of pollution abatement is estimated to be only moderate. Also, this form of subsidy is inefficient because such assistance provides an incentive for excessive use of capital and practically excludes similar assistance to process changes that jointly reduce pollution and increase productivity. Moreover, such aid is likely to be an undesirable precedent for using tax writeoffs for other programs (e. g. , education, training, housings etc. ). Performance grants, emission charges and^effluent fees are not now feasible for widespread use. They must await the development of adequate institutions, improved monitoring methods and better pollution damage estimates. When these obstacles are overcome, performance grants and fees are the:type of incentives that would be most efficient and augment effective enforcement. However, it is important to experiment with their use now while awaiting the evolution of more effective pollution management organizations. ------- -4- On equity grounds, assistance could be offered industrial plants that experience real hardship or assistance, could be broadened to include, all plants that experience high abatement costs per unit of output. A program of aid to firms that experience severe hardship could be implemented within the programs administered by the Economic Development Administration (EDA), Small Business Administration (SBA) programs; Interior and HEW. EDA can give loans to firms of any size in designated areas or outside those areas if pollution control expenditures threaten the viability of a firm and a community. Over 95% of the businesses in the United States are eligible for SBA assistance -- from the smallest to some of the larger companies. In addition, study funds used to identify feasible ways for plants to meet quality standards would be desirable. All of these approaches would augment the enforcement process. At the present time, further assistance in addition to current Federal programs is unnecessary and undesirable for industry as a whole. However, assistance for planus and firms unable to obtain funds for pollution abatement capital expenditures or in need of pollution abatement technical aid can. be justified on both equity and efficiency grounds. RECOMMENDATIONS 1. The Secretary of Health, Education, and Welfare and the Secretary's of the Interior should examine the goals and effectiveness of programs already available for controlling industrial pollution and recommend changes in their administration and content to make these programs more effective. Also the level of assistance already offered to industry should be highlighted -- such as the 7% investment tax credit, technical assistance, personnel training, and R&D expenditures for lowering the cost of abatement. 2. The Federal Government should consider increasing its investment in research and development in the following areas: a. More economic methods of industrial pollution abatement. b. Evaluation of alternative institutional arrangements for implementation of pollution abatement programs. c. More effective devices for measuring waste load discharges and concentration levels. d. Measurement of damages caused by pollution. ------- - 5 - e. Better estimates of the cost and performance of alternative abatement measures within firms and within problem shed areas. f. Technical bottleneck areas such as desulphurization of coal and acid mine drainage. 3. Additional assistance in meeting required pollution abatement standards is recommended only in cases where cost of abatement imposes a demonstrable hardship on individual plants which were located prior to 1967-- when the Clean Air Act was passed and water quality standards were required. Consideration should be given to the importance of hardship plants in each community. Current programs administered by the Economic Development Administration, Small Business Administration, Interior, and HEW could accommodate this recommendation. 4. Across-the-board cost-sharing in the form of tax writeoffs is not recommended because it distorts the tax structure, causes the total cost of pollution abatement to rise significantly, promotes ex- cessive use of capital equipment and waste treatment facilities, and discourages selectivity in environmental quality management. Across-the- board use of grants and loans is similarly handicapped and, in addition, is subject to fluctuations in Congressional appropriations- ------- -6- PRESENT FEDERAL ASSISTANCE General Assistance The Federal Government at the present time extends significant amounts of assistance to industry. Therefore, it should not be thought that industry is facing the total cost of pollution abatement alone. General assistance is offered to industry under the 7% investment tax credit for capital equipment. This credit extends to all capital equip- ment investment, including those for air and water pollution control, and has the effect of reducing the net cost of air and water pollution control facilities to industrial firms. Perhaps $10-25 Million of assistance is given each year in this way to manufacturing firms investing in pollution abatement equipment. Also air and water pollution control equipment is included under the accelerated depreciation allowances for capital equipment -- such as double declining balance and sum->of-the-digits. The effect is similar to an interest-free loan for the amounts involved. The current annual subsidy through this provision may be $15-30 million for manufacturing firms investing in pollution control facilities. Water Pollution Abatement Assistance The national program of water pollution control rests primarily with the Department of Interior, with ancillary programs in the Corps of Engineers (DOD), the Departments of Commerce and Housing and Urban Development. The Interior Department program includes grants for comprehensive river basin planning, research, development, demonstration, training, research fellowships, and construction expenditures for new municipal waste treatment facilities (See Table I). The State grants assist States and interstate agencies in establishing and maintaining adequate measures for the prevention and control of water pollution. Funds appropriated to the States are allotted by statutory provision on the basis of population and per capita income. The grants and contracts for research, development and demonstra- tion projects are aimed at developing new and improved methods for the prevention and control of water pollution. In the water pollution control program, the total annual appropriation currently is $53 million. At least $10 million of this amount is allocated for industrial waste problems. The Clean Water Restoration Act of 19&6 specifically authorized demonstration ------- -7- TABLE I Federal Water Pollution Control Budget (FY 1968 New Obligational Authority Estimate) (Millions of dollars) GRANTS: Research and Development $37^0 Training $ 4.0 State Program and Planning Grants $10.5 Construction Grants $203.0 DIRECT OPERATIONS $ 41.0 TOTAL $295.5 Source: Federal Water Pollution Control Administration, Interior. ------- -8- grants in three categories: (a) storm and combined sewers, (b) advanced waste treatment and joint treatment systems for municipal and industrial waste, and (c) methods for prevention of pollution by industry, including, but not limited to, treatment of industrial waste. Grants may not exceed 75% of the project cost. The training grants, contracts and research fellowships are aimed at encouraging, cooperating with and assisting agencies, institutions, and individuals in the control and prevention of water pollution. There are four types of grants -- (a) research grants which support basic and applied research projects throughout the country and encourage investigators to explore neglected areas in the causes and controls and prevention of water pollution; (b) research fellowships which promote specialized training in the problems of water pollution; (c) training grants which expand training programs in universities, colleges, and institutions; and (d) demonstration grants which develop and support projects aimed at accelerating application of new knowledge to routine water pollution control practices. The waste treatment grants are intended to accelerate construction of local waste treatment facilities. Under the Federal Water Pollution Control Act, as amended, grants can be made to any State, municipality, intermunicipality or interstate agency for the construction of waste treatment plants, including intercepting and outfall sewers. Grants for municipal waste treatment facilities vary from 30% to 55%. Industrial firms benefit to the extent they seek waste treatment service from municipalities, for they obtain economies of scale, convenience, and the avoidance of most of the capital-raising requirements. This assistance is limited, however, according to the ability and willingness of the municipality to provide tffl.fi..service and by the limitations of Federal funds to assist the municipality in financing the construction. For fiscal year 1968, $203 million has been appropriated. The total additional annual cost needed to provide secondary treatment for all municipalities is estimated to be about $900 million or about $6 per person living in an^irban area. The total additional capital investment required to reach this level is estimated to be $6. 8 billion. Coupled with investment necessary to replace existing facilities, the total becomes $8.0 billion required during the next 5 to 10 years. The most significant assistance to industry for water pollution control is the construction grant program for municipal waste treatment plants. Industrial firms may negotiate a price.from the municipality for the waste service that covers only the costs the municipality itself meets. That is, the price for the service may reflect the Federal grant and thus constitute a considerable subsidy. Moreover, many municipalities do not require industrial firms to cover their proportion of capital costs. Therefore ------- -9- these municipalities are subsidizing industry too. The effect of the subsidized price may be to induce carelessness on the part of the firm in regard to waste controls and disposal. The result could be a larger waste load at the municipal plant. The impact on the Federal budget could be to require higher appropriations under the municipal construction grant program to meet the consequently larger scale municipal facilities. The encouragement of full-cost pricing by municipalities to induce effective industrial waste controls and to achieve real economies of scale is important. The aim of the Corps of Engineers' water quality control program is to improve water quality by the timely release of water from storage reservoirs. While the law prohibits the specific use of flow augmentation as a substitute for adequate treatment or control of wastes, it does, nevertheless, provide authority for building reser- voir capacity for stream flow regulation. In these cases*, the entire cost allocated to water quality control has been assumed by the Federal Government when the benefits were considered to be widespread. However, this arrangement is now under .critical review. Hydrologic and hydrometeorological data and analyses are provided for State and local government, communities, and industry concerned with planning, management, and conservation of water resources. Other forms of technical assistance are also provided. Air Pollution Abatement Assistance Air pollution control, under the primary jurisdiction of the Depart- ment of Health, Education and Welfare, promotes control of air pollu- tion through a variety of activities, including research, training, technical assistance, and grants and aids to State, local and regional government agencies. (See Table II and III). Direct Federal abatement activities are undertaken to remedy certain interstate and intrastate problems. Technical assistance is provided for resolving specific air pollution problems. Funds for community surveys and control program plans are available to State and local governmental agencies. Grants are made for development, improvement, establishment and, under new legislation, maintenance of abatement control programs. Grants to universities support advanced training programs. Fellowships are offered to prospective managers of governmental and industrial control programs. Research grants support basic scientific inquiry. The Commerce Department's Environmental Science Services Administration through its Weather Bureau disseminates weather summaries which warn of impending, potentially hazardous accumulations of pollution. ------- -10- TABLE II Federal Air Pollution Budget (FY 1968 New Obligational Authority Estimate)-^ (Millions of dollars) Research ~ Stand- and .m " Train- ards Infor- nn^*- T«i-oi , , stration . „ , Other Total develop- jest inS Regu- mation raent lations Sulphur Dioxide $ 8.A $ 7.9 $0 $0 $0 $0 $16.3 Vehicle Emissions 4.3 0 0 1.9 0 0 6.2 Other Non-Allocable 14.9 1.5 4.8 6.1 1^6 24.9 53.8 TOTAL $27.6 $9.4 $4.8 $8.4 $1.6 $24.9 $76.3 a/ Includes only Federal Funds Managed by HEW. Source: Health, Education and Welfare. ------- -11- TABLE IH State and Local Expenditure for Air Pollution Control (FY 1967) Total Program Federal Local State Budget Grants Expenditures California $5,317,141 $391,483 $4,925,758 Illinois 1,475,876 522,500 953,376 Michigan 796,370 370,918 425,452 New Jersey- 827,021 260,960 566,061 New York 5,466, 768 608,714 4, 858, 054. Pe nnsy 1 vania 1,279,334 453,086 826,248 Total 6 States $15,162,510 $2,607,661 $13,554,849 TOTAL ALL STATES $22,121,364 $6,378,179 $15,743,185 Source: Health, Education and Welfare ------- -12- CURRENT COSTS OF POLLUTION CONTROL FOR MANUFACTURING FIRMS Industrial plants have invested regularly in pollution abatement facilities and techniques prior to the passage of the Water Quality Act of 1965 and the Clean Air Act of 1967. However, as called for by the provisions of these acts, additional expenditures will be required. But before proceeding to the likely increase in these expenditures, it should be emphasized that industry has invested and is continuing to invest in facilities to reduce the discharge of harmful ^vaste loads. In the case of water pollution abatement, the Federal Water Pollu- tion Control Administration (FWPCA), through its study of industrial waste treatment profiles has estimated the replacement value of exist- ing industrial waste treatment facilities to be approximately $2 billion; another $. 7 billion represents the replacemeht value of that portion of municipal facilities allocated for treatment of industrial wastes. In 1966, the annual cost to industry for water pollution control is estimated to have been $642 million. This represents .294% of total value-added by manufacturing plants in 1966 (see Table IV). However, these figures do not include built-in water pollution controls provided in the design of new processing units. Although not a burden of industry, but certainly a benefit, no estimate is made of the Federal pollution control expendi- tures for reservoirs which improve water quality by the regulation of flows. In the case of air pollution abatement, there are no acceptable na- tional estimates of total investment or annual cost. Quest for Better Data During the summer of 1967, an effort was made through the National Industrial Conference Board (NICB) to obtain waste control cost data by sample survey techniques. A questionnaire was developed in collabora- tion with NICB and tested for feasibility on a small sample of 30 firms with 110 plants. The result was disappointing due, in part, to the com- plexity of the questions, the reluctance of the firms to answer questions on their financial situation, and the lack of knowledge of likely waste con- trol requirements. A more carefully constructed questionnaire was in- dicated from this experience after firms have had time to analyze their own abatement requirements under the water quality standards and the anticipated air quality standards. Further study is being given to this method, but questionnaire results do not appear likely for 1968. Pessimism toward this approach is height- ened by the fact that the firms selected for the pilot study were chosen on ------- -13- TABLE IV Estimate of Replacement Cost, Annual Cost, and Burden of Water Waste Treatment Facilities for Manufacturing, 1966 Current Replacement Cost: Industrial Waste Treatment Facilities Portion of Municipal Facilities used by Industrial Plants TOTAL $2, 000 million 700 million $2, 700 million Annual Cost: Capital cost of industrial waste treatment facilities (amortization over 20 years at 6% interest) Operation and maintenance cost TOTAL for industrial waste treatment Capital cost of portion of municipal facilities used by industrial plants (Amortization over 25 years at 4-1/2% interest) Operations and maintenance cost of the portion of municipal facilities used by industrial plants TOTAL for industrial portion of municipal facilities TOTAL for Manufacturing Annual industrial abatement as a percent of total value-added by manufacturing in 1966 ($218. 6 billion) $172 million 380 million $ 47 million 43 million $ 552 million 90 million $ 642 million . 294% Source: Data from Federal Water Pollution Control Administration, and the Commerce Department, ------- -14- the basis of the interest which they had indicated to the National Indus- trial Conference Board about air pollution problems. These firms should have been able to answer a pollution questionnaire more readily than other firms which have been less concerned about the problem. UIKELY ADDITIONAL ABATEMENT COSTS Estimates of the additional abatement costs are much more difficult to determine for air than for water. For air, there are no precise measures of total needed abatement, while in the case of water, needed abatement can be more accurately estimated because of the observable trend in the level of water quality standards. However, the recently enacted Clean Air Act of 1967 will help to overcome this deficiency in laying the groundwork for the establishment of air quality standards. Even for water, one of the estimates below is based on an across-the- board 85% level of treatment with all abatement being accomplished by end-of-line treatment plants and with no consideration of hydrology or actual river standards. Future cost of abatement will be significantly affected by the way in which waste reductions are required and the degree to which more effective institutions for the enforcement of abatement come into exist-, ence. In the case of the Delaware River Basin, for example, FWPCA found that simple equal-proportional reduction of all waste loads -- could cause an increase of 50% in the total cost to achieve the same quality standard compared to the cost estimated by requiring firms to reduce their waste loads in proportion to their harmful effects. But in the case of air, the cost could increase by 200% to 400% if equal-proportional reduction year-round is proposed. Where the design of abatement plants can take advantage of the assimilative capacity and variations in volume of flowing water, the cost is significantly affected in achieving any given water quality standards; concerning air, the dilution capacity and daily flow conditions could affect the cost of control even more. Additional Costs of Water Pollution Control The Federal Water Pollution Control Administration of the Depart- ment of the Interior sought to attain better information on the additional cost of control through the use of consultants. The consultants developed reports and analyses on 10 industrial sectors, accounting for 95% of the ------- -15- 2/ large water users in manufacturing. The reports related waste units to production units and waste reduction or treatment to costs. The exper- ience of the consultants augmented by data from previous studies of selected problems and the Census Bureau's manufacturing production, water use, and waste water disposal data constituted the frame of reference of the analyses. The FWPCA staff evaluation of the reports carefully states the limitations of the data and cautions against conclusions of a definitive and final nature. Also the hypothetical standards employed for determining costs were used for computational purposes andoobviously should not be interpreted as a desirable abatement strategy to meet standards. Never- theless, this effort constitutes the first attempt at a systematic, comprehensive survey of industrial liquid waste treatment costs. The findings of the FWPCA studies indicate that the annual cost for abatement will rise by $275 million to attain a hypothetical standard requiring 85% removal of biochemical oxygen demanding (BOD) wastes and suspended solids. Two-thirds of the total annual cost, or $181 million, is required for operation and maintenance cost and the remaining one-third, or $94 million, is for capital cost. The additional burden estimated for all manufacturing firms is . 126% of total value-added by manufacturing firms (see Table V). This is rather an insignificant cost increase when compared to the more than 6% increase in average hourly compensation in manufacturing that occurred in 1967. Even after adjusting for productivity changes -- 0. 9% additional output per man-hour -- unit labor cost rose by over 5% and was a major contributor in increasing the cost of manufacturing by roughly 3%. If manufacturing firms continue to use municipal waste facilities as they do now, then 21%, or $38 million., of the additional annual cost can be expected to be paid through assessments and fees to municipal waste treatment organizations. This may be, however, an overstate- ment of the cost because municipal waste tr^atrpent plants may be sub- sidized by Federal construction grants and in addition there is reason to suspect that municipalities do not charge manufacturing firms their full proportion of both capital and operating costj, Also, manufacturing firms may increase their use of municipal facilities as concentration of both industry and people continues. 2/ Food and Kindred Products; Textile Mill Products; Paper and Allied Products; Chemicals and Allied Products; Petroleum and Coal Products; Rubber and Plastics Products; Primary Metals, Blast Furnaces; Primary Metals and Steel Mills, all others; Electrical Machinery; All Other Machinery; Transportation Equipment. ------- TABLE V Estimate of Additional Annual Cost of Water Pollution Abatement to Meet a Hypothetical Industrial Water Quality Standard Requiring 85% Removal of Biochemical Oxygen Demanding Wastes & Suspended Solids (million of dollars) Current Additional New Percent of Annual Annual Annual Total Annual Cost (1966)b Cost Cost Cost Add col (1) and (2) (1) (2) (3) (4) Capital Costs :a Manufacturing waste treatment facilities $172 74c $246 27% Portion of municipal facilities used by manufacturers 47 20 67 7% Total 219 94 313 34% Operation and Maintenance Costs: Manufacturing waste treatment facilities 380 163 543 59% Portion of municipal facilities used by 0V f manufacturers 43 18 61 7% Total 423 181 604 66% Total Cost $642 $275 $917 100% Average burden on manufacturing firms*, Percent of total value added by manu- facturing in 1966 ($218. 6billion) . 294% . 126% .420% « — a/Amortized over 20 years at 6% interest for industry and over 25 years at 4-1/2% for municipalities b/See Table IV c/Assuming the same proportional use of municipal facilities and that manufacturers actually pay fees adequate, to cover capital costs SQurce: Data from Federal Water Pollution Control Administration and Commerce. ------- -17- Manufacturing firms will be required to increase the rate of in- vestment for waste treatment facilities. The additional capital expendi- ture to reach the hypothetical standard with the current level of industrial output and mix of industries is estimated to be $1.15 billion. This could cause some problems for some firms in obtaining funds to make the needed investment. If manufacturing firms are consistent with their past behavior, roughly one-fifth of the capital needs will be satisfied through use of municipal facilities. If the remaining capital investment is made in the first five year's with only capital replacement expenditures for the remaining 15 yearB of the economic life of the new-investment, the demand for additional funds (cash flow) would increase from $275 million to $468 million for each of the fir^t five ^fears and then decrease to $201 for each of the next 15 years. Even at the higher level, requirements for new funds to achieve the hypothetical standard would only amount to . 214% of total value-adfled by manufacturing -- which is hardly a serious burden oh all manufacturers. In future years, as population and industry concentrate more extensively around the Nation's rivers and lakes, abatement cost will undoubtedly rise. For example, if the hypothetical standard is raised from 85% to 90% removal of BOD and suspended solids by waste treatment plants, then additional annual abatement costs are estimated to be approximately $413 million, or .189% of total value-added by manufacturing firms. Should the extremely high level of 95% removal of BOD and suspended solids be achieved, the annual costs are estimated to rise to $715 million or . 313% of total value-added. The conclusion from this pioneering study is that the additional annual burden or the additional cash flow requirement for manufacturing, on the average, is likely to be small. However, industries and firms within manufacturing will face costs which will vary considerably from the average. For example, the chemical industry is likely to spend nearly four times the average while the machine industry will likely . spend less than one-fourth (see Table VI). The additional burden upon manufacturing industries is estimated to vary from nearly zero to . 5% of total manufacturing output. For each firm on each plant the variation of additional annual costs will undoubtedly be greater. It is interesting to note that many of the industries facing the largest increase in expenditures are generally the same,ones that have already made large expenditures. Also, these same industries -- e. g. , chemicals, foods, and steel mills -- have a history of reducing waste discharges by improving production processes so as to reduce the creation of waste loads as well as investing in the more conventional wapte treatment facilities. ------- -18- TABLE VI Comparison of Waste Treatment Required and Distribution of Value of Manufacturing Output Assuming Hypothetical Wast^ Treatment of 85% of Biochemical Oxygen Demanding Wastes and Suspended Solids, 1966 Industries Percent of Total Manu- facturing Output Percent of Total Additional Waste Treatment Required Variation in Burden as a percent of Average Burden Col (2) -S- Col (1) (1) (2) (3) Food and Kindred Products 16.61 20. 91 126 Textile Mill Products 3.86 2. 52 65 Paper and Allied Products 4. 12 7.20 175 Chemical and Allied Products 7.32 26.60 363 Petroleum and Coal Products 3.88 7. 32 189 Rubber and Plastics Products 2,41 2. 94 122 Primary Metals, Blast Furnaces 4.49 9. 34 208 Primary Metals, Steel Mills and 4. 15 4.88 118 All Other Machinery Electrical 7.54 . 81 11 Machinery, All Others 7.61 2.37 31 Transportation Equipment 13. 90 3. 96 28 All Other Manufacturing 24.11 11. 15 46 Source: Data from Federal Water Pollution Control Administration and Commerce Department. ------- -19- Therefore, the costs from this study are obviously higher than can be expected. An Alternative Estimate of the Additional Cost of Water Pollution Control In 1966, FWPCA prepared a preliminary report of a comprehensive water quality control study of the Delaware River Estuary. The study was developed with the cooperation of industrial firms using the estuary for waste disposal. Some consideration was given to process changes within manufacturing plants, to the assimilative capacity of the estuary for waste disposal and to water quality criteria related to some specific uses of the estuary such as quality levels to insure success of the annual shad run through critical areas. In this respect the Delaware Study is more refined than the industrial profiles. The estimated additional cost to achieve the high water quality standard since established for the estuary is $15 million annually if marginal costs to all polluters are equated by means of an effluent charge or by means of selective levels of reduction. If uniform treatment is required then the cost increases by 50% to $24 million. Roughly two-thirds of the total cost is for operation and maintenance; one-third is for the estimated annual capital cost. Although different hydrologic characteristics and quality standards apply in the other major drainage basins in the country, an indication of what the national cost is likely to be can be obtained by extrapolating cost patterns of the industrial firms in the Delaware Estuary to all manufacturing firms on the basis of waste water discharged. This method of estimating the additional annual cost for all manufacturing gives a figure of $234 million. If all firms are required to removeind equal percentage of wastes produced before discharging the remainder to the water body, the cost increases by 50% to $374 million. The additional burden on manufacturing plants is only . 107% to . 171% of total value- added. (See Table VII). The results are similar to those obtained by the industrial waste profiles and reinforces the conclusion that the burden of water pollution abatement is likely to be m'odest. The Additional Cost of Air Pollution Control In order to estimate the additional cost of air pollution control, the National Center for Air Pollution Control with the assistance of a consulting firm constructed a simulation model of a "typical" major city ------- -20- TABLE VII Additional Annual Cost to Achieve the Water Quality Standarda Established for the Delaware River Estuary and an Extrapolation for All Manufacturing Firms Based on Waste Water Discharged by Manufacturers in the Estuary and the Country, 1966 (millions of dollars) Capital Cost Operatiors and Maintenance T otal Percent of Total Value Added by Manufacturing in 1966 f$218. 4 billion) Estuary All Manufacturing Uniform Charge for All Wastes Actually Uniform Uniform Charge for All Wastes Actually $ 5 10 15 $ 8 16 24 $ 76 156 234 107% Uniform Discharged Treatment Discharged Treatment $ 123 251 374 171% a/ Summer average dissolved oxygen of 4 parts per million gallons in the critical sections of the estuary. b/ Amortized over 20 years at 6 percent interest. cj The effect of the charge was to require only harmful waste loads be reduced by the least costly method. d/ All dischargers remove an equal percentage of the wastes produced before discharging the remainder to the steam. Source: Data from the Federal Water Pollution Control Administration's Delaware Estuary Study ai*d the Commerce Department. ------- -21- experiencing air quality problems. The model of two million people included realistic discharges of sulphur oxides (SOx) and particulates from coal and oil fueled electric power plants, multi-family and single family residential space heating units, a non-ferrous foundry, a petroleum refinery, a sulphuric acid plant and a municipal incinerator. The waste loads were scaled down from a rough approximation of waste loads emitted by a larger city -- New York. Industry that is not found in New York was included to make the model city more typical, such as the non-ferrous foundry and the sulphuric acid plant. The dispersion of waste loads generated was determined by the height of smoke stacks and a "typical" meteorological model -- based upon St. Louis. Costs were collected for various techniques and technologies useable for reducing harmful waste discharges. As a proxy for future air quality standards.emissioif were cut back so as to reduce human exposure from SOx and particulates. Human exposure was measured by the number of people multiplied times the parts per million of SO^ and particulates. The additional annual cost of efficiently reducing human SO and particulate: exposure by 60-75% from the present level was estimated to be approximately $11 million for the "typical" city and $769 million for the United States (See Table VIII). Approximately 85% of the cost is in the form of increased fuel, operations, and maintenance costs. Because of the heavy use of fuel substitution, the capital cost is estimated to be less than 15% of the total cost. However, other studies by NCAPC indicate that the proportion of capital cost to total cost increases at higher abatement levels. The cost of abating particulates appears to be cheaper than reducing SO by the same proportion. In the model city study less than 20% of the toteil cost of achieving the hypothetical quality standard is attributable to particulate control alone. It should be recognized that not all of these costs will be borne by manufacturers and utilities. Households, other industrial firms and other commercial firms will undoubtedly bear a large proportion -- probably about 54%. So all of the cost estimates should be adjusted downward for industry's likely burden. If manufacturers and electric power plants account for only 46% of the additional cost, then the additional burden will be 0.16% of value-added by manufacturing and electric power production. ------- -22- TABLE VIII g / Annual Cost- of Achieving a Hypothetical Standard by Reducing Human Exposure of Sulphur Oxides and Particulates by 60 to 75% in a "Typical City" of 2 Million People and Extrapolated for the United States, 1967 (Millions of dollars) Typical Citv United States?!/ Least Cost—/ Propor- tional Reduction^ Least Cost Propor- tional Reduction Capital Cost $1.17 $2.29 $81.90 $160.30 Operations and maintenance 9.81 15.78 686.70 1,104.60 TOTAL $10.98 $18.07 $768.60 $1,264.90 Cost to Industry—i Percent of value added 5.05 8.31 353.56 0.16% 581.85 0.26% Cost to others^/- Per Capita Percent of per capita incomeS/. 5.93 9.76 415.04 2.96 0.11% 683.05 4.88 V 0.18% a/ Includes cost from substituting fuels, purchasing more costly lower sulphur-content fuel, and treatment of emissions whichever is cheaper for each emitter. b/ Only those discharging harmful waste loads and technically able to reduce waste loads were required to abate in the simulation. c/ All waste load emitters must reduce waste discharges by the same proportion, d/ Assumed same air quality conditions hold for all Standard Metropolitan Statistical Areas -- 70% of the nation's population of 200 milliori. e/ All manufacturing, incinerators and electric power companies if abatement costs were allocated as a proportion of waste loads emmitted. if Almost entirely fpr space heating. g/ Per Capita Disposable Income for the entire country was $2,735 in 1967. h/ In dollars -- e.g. 2.96 dollars and 4.88 dollars. Source: Data from National Center for Air Pollution Control's "Typical" City Study and the Commerce Department. ------- -23- In the case of both air and water, there will be wide variations in the cost of abatement and in the relative burden for particular plants and industries. The range is undoubtedly greater in air than in the case of water. As indicated by the model, if enforcement is pursued by asking all waste load emitters to abate whether they actually contribute to lowering the hypothetical air quality standard in each air shed, the annual additional cost doubles. Moreover, proportional reduction will impact most severely on electric power plants w^iich are heavy emitters but not necessarily heavy polluters. Other studies have shown that the cost can quadruple if seasonality and other facitors are not considered. An Alternative Partial Cost Estimate: Twenty City Model of Electric Power Plants Data were collected from power plants in the twenty cities with serious sulphur oxide problems.—' Each power plant was identified by distance and direction from the center of population density in each city;, type (e. g. , coal, oil or gas), quantity, sulphur content, and seasonality of fuel consumed; age of major physical facilities, wind vector (direction and speed) in the vicinity of each plant (air shed), and height of smokestacks. Several abatement strategies were simulated for two fuel standards based upon two levels of minimum sulphur content in coal and oil. Tbe study showed that raising the severity of the fuel standard from 1. 5% sulphur-content for Chicago, New York and Philadelphia and 2^0% for the other cities to 1. 0% for the big three and 1. 5% for the other cities increased the fuel affected by at least one-third and the cost by one-fifth. However, the choice of abatement strategies has the greatest impact. If all plants are forced to use low-sulphur fuel as opposed to those that are actually emitting harmful waste loads, the fuel affected rises by over 100%. For example, if all plants located on the upwind 3/Chicago, Cleveland, Los Angeles, Long Beach, New York, Newark, Jersey City, Philadelphia, Boston, Detroit, Pittsburgh, St. Louis, Baltimore, Cincinnati, Gary-Hammond-East Chicago, Indianapolis, Louisville, Milwaukee, and Washington, D. C. ------- -24- side of each city and those within 5 miles on the downwind side are asked to abate, only 43% of the oil and 44% of the coal is affected and cost rises by $27 million (See Table IX). If fuel restrictions are placed on all plants, 96% of the oil and 95% of the coal will be affected and the cost rises by $59 million. The high stacks, jet exhaust effect and location of plants downwind from population centers are the reason for the dramatic difference in impact. It is conceivable that the harmful discharges from power plants are located upwind of the center of town and the bther power plants are not major contributors to unacceptable sulphur oxide or particulate con- centrations during most of the year. If this is so, enforcement could pinpoint these'fuels and only affect 9% of oil and ,24% of coal consumed and cause an increase in cost of only $13 million -- or only 22% of the cost of proportional reduction. During the 3-10 days when calm winds cause all sources of waste loads to be potentially harmful, plants could switch to low-sulphur fuels temporarily. This strategy is considerably less expensive than asking plants at all locations to abate all year around. The cost of abatement can be greatly affected by the opportunity to build-in pollution abatement devices when new electric power plants are constructed as compared to adding on abatement facilities to existing plants. The normal expectation of replacement of plants within five years is estimated to be only 15% of capacity while the expected replacement within 10 years is estimated to be one-third of capacity. 4/ 2 4/ Installed Capacity (millions of kilowatt hours) =? 30. 0557 t 2.8996t + . 25l67t Additions = 1. 6159 + • 5704t Retirement = . 0312 + . 0337t Adjustment =,r. 11569 + . 05002t t = 0 =1946; assumed capacity unalterable until 1970. ------- -25- TABLE IX Affected Fuel and Hypothesized Cost of Achieving Fuel Standards for Electric Power Generation Plants Liocated in or near the Twenty Cities with the Worst Sulphur Oxide Problem, 1967 Abatement Strategy for each city 1. All Plants 2. All Plants within 10 miles of center of city 3. Plants located East within 5 miles and West within 10 miles Mild Restrictionsa Fuel affected as a percent Total Fuel Consumed Oil Coal 83% 57 43 78% 51 37 Additional Annual Costc ($ Millions) Oil Coal $10.15 $38. 96 6.90 25.71 5.22 18.59 Total $49.11 32. 61 23. 81 Severe Restrictions Fuel affected as a percent Total Fuel Consumed Additional Annual Costc. ($ Millions) Oil 43 Coal Oil Coal 96% 95% $11.69 $47.44 57 58 6.97 29.18 44 5.29 22.06 Total $59. 13 36.15 27. 35 4. Plants located West 27 37 3.33 18.46 21. 79 33 48 4.00 24.24 28 . Zf 5. Plants located South- we st 24 26 2.92 13.15 16.07 29 34 3.57 17.11 20. 68 6. Plants located North - we st 3 11 41 5.30 5. 71 14 42 7.13 7. 55 7. Plants in quadrant of prevailing winds 21 41 10.29 10.70 24 1.06 12.11 13.17 a) Mild sulphur content restrictions: I. 5% for Chicago, New York and Philadelphia; 2. 0% for all other cities. b) Severe sulphur content restrictions: 1.0% for Chicago, New York and Philadelphia; 1. 5% for all other cities.- c) Assumed 10% for oil and 15% for coal Source: Data from Federal Power Commission and Weather Bureau. ------- -26- POSSIBLE ADDITIONAL FEDERAL SUBSIDIES Introduction It was noted that the Federal Government is now spending $1/2 billion per year for both air and water pollutioii abatement and this amount is forecast to increase markedly during the next five years. The largest proportion of these funds are now funneled through municipalities. Industry also receives considerable assistance from the 7% investment tax credit and allowances for accelerated depreciation -- perhaps as high as $50 million annually. The size of current annual expenditures by industry for water pollution abatement is roughly estimated at $2/3 billion for water and an unknown amount for air -- or perhaps roughly equal to the current Federal Governmeit expenditure and subsidy for this area. The Government is already carrying a large part of the burden. The requirement for additional expenditures is a function of water and air quality standards, plant location, typography, stream capacity, meteorology, production processes, and pollutants. Before all of these factors are weighed, only some rough estimates of additional annual cost and burden for manufacturing can be made: $275 million and 0.13% of value-added ty manufacturing for water and $354 million for air -- or $629 million and 0. 29% of value-added for both air and\vwater (excluding thermal-pollution abatement). For individual industries, firms and plant3 the burden ie likely to vary widely. Finally, it is not clear that pollution abatement need affect the firms' rate of profit insofar as individual firms have considerable flexibility to shift the small increase in the costs from themselves to the purchasers of their products. It is with this summary and introduction in mind that the possible Federal subsidies will be examined. Tax Writeoffs Numerous proposals in Congress have been made for offering greater assistance to industry through increasing the investment tax credit or accelerating the depreciation allowances on capital expenditures for pollu- tion abatement. Proposals range from increasing the investment tax credit from 7% to 14% or 20% and/or from allowing depreciation allowances normally scheduled over 15 years to be scheduled over five, three or even one year. The additional capital subsidy would range from 7% for raising ------- -27- the investment tax credit to 14% to 33% for implementing a 20% tax credit and a one-year accelerated depreciation schedule. {See Table X), The subsidy would total roughly $296 million for water and $75 million for aii for the three-year accelerated depreciation allowance if applied to an estimate of-the additional capital required to meet the hypothetical standards considered in this report. However, the subsidy is in a small part illusoty because the assistance would be given for a higher level of expenditure caused by the Bubsidy creating an incentive to over-use capital to thie neglect of operating and maintenance expenditures. This would arise because capital costs are madeaa-Jdfifcially cheaper by Virtue of a tax writeoff. Tax writeoffs are handicapped because they are incapable of,providing assistance to all of the coats of abatement. The capital cost accounts for roughly one- third of the total cost for water pollution abatement and one-eighth for air pollution abatement. Of course, with subsidies given to capital alone, the capital cost proportion will tend to ri^e afid unnecessarily consume more resources. The addition of chemicals or supervisory personnel often times is less costly than building additional capacity in order to treat larger waste loads. Fuel substitution alone is estimated to be the least-(nrest alternative in over 60% of the cases involving air pollution abatement. Moreover, tax writeoffs are difficult to apply to many changes in the production process which reduce the actual generation of waste loads but which also add to the output of plants. Other studies have shown that some industries find that over 50% of the least-costly opportunities for ^ducing waste load discharges are found in such process changes.— The Treasury Department would be faced with the difficult task of certifying the proportion or the cost attributable for pollution abatement or disallowing any assistance for this kiaadcdf improvement . To the extent of the proportion disallowed, plants would be given an incentive to ignore many improvements which have been shown to be least costly. Also, the implementation of selective writeoffs for pollution abate- ment opens the door for other programs to receive similar treatment. Proposals for tax writeoffs for training, education, mining, transportation, housing and others have already been made. The snowballing effect for industry could be, conceivably, a necessary increase in the corporate tax structure or lag in the long-run reduction of corporate tax rates and thus no net benefit to firms facing pollution abatement expenditures. Moreover, public accountability of such subsidies, are difficult and would probably create an annoying problem in its removal once social policy dictates a change. _5/ For example in the case of water, see Kneese, Allen and Lof, George. The Economics of Water Utilization in the Beet Sugar Industry, Manuscript, Resources for the Future. ------- TABLE X Comparison of the Additional Subsidy to Industry ^hrough Alternative Forms of Federal Assistance- Type of Assistance Subsidy as Percent of Capital Cost Subsidy as a Percent of Animal Cost- Rough Estimate of likely Assistance to Industry for Capital Expenditures to Meet Hypothetical Standards in 5 Years 1969-1973^' ($ Minions) t-f~ Accelerated Depreciation: Additional Tax Credits: 5 years 13% 3 years 16 1 year 20 14% 7 20% 13 Water Air 5% 6 9 2 5 2% 3 4 1 2 Water—/ 241 296 370 130 241 Air—1 61 75 94 33 61 Accelerated Depreciation and Tax Credit Combined: 14% tax credit and 3 year accelerated depreciation 23 20% tax credit and 1 year accelerated depreciation 33 Reduced interest loans. y 10 17 5 8 426 611 108 155 i OJ 00 1 6% {3% below discount rate. 4% {5%'below discount rate). 11 17 4 7 2 3 204 315 52 80 a/ Assume 48% effective tax rate, 15 year functional life (straight line) for pollution abatement facilities and 9% discount rate. Excluding accelerated depreciation now available in existing tax laws -- e.g. , sum of digitsor double' declining balance. b/ 15 years, straight reduction loan, 9% discount rate for industry (if assume 6% then zero gain for 6% inter- est loan and 7% or $71 million gain for 4% interest loan). c/ Includes annual capital cost (amortized) and operation and maintenance expenditures, increase in total cost of abatement because of excessive use of artificially cheaper capital costs. d/ Assuming all capital expenditures are subsidized whether to industry or households. Capital costs would undoubtedly drop after the initial investments are made to achieve standards. e/ Based on industrial profiles: $1. 15 billion additional investment plus $. 7 billion replacement investment which equals $1. 85 for BOD and suspended solids for hypothetical standard of 85% treatment of industrial wastes, f / Assuming 20 years of additional capital investment is made in 5 years. The total capital as indicated by the "Typical City" Study should be $470 million to achieve a hypothetical standard of reducing human exposure by 60-7 5% of SO and Particulates. ------- -29- In summary, clearly tax writeoffs are not needed nor are they a desirable form for offering further assistance to industry. Grants and Loans for Industry Demonstration grants for industrial water pollution abatement, are now provided under the Federal Water Pollution Control Act and for air pollution abatement under the Air Quality Act. Feasibility study grants and capital grants have been proposed. Furthermore, programs have been proposed for-ro1^interest loans. Grants and loans have the same goals as tax writeoffs in that they usually are designed to lower the cost of capital expenditures only. As in the case of tax writeoffs, subsidization limited to capital expenditures will provide assistance for only a small proportion of the likely total cost of abatement -- 17% for a 33% capital investment goal for water and 8% for a 33% capital investment grant for air (See Table X). Moreover, the total cost is likely to rise through unbalanced subsidization of inputs and the likely exclusion of production process changes. In addition, certification of expenditures would impose a distasteful chore for Government and industry alike. However, if grants were made for both capital and operating costs and administered on the basis of river basin and regional air quality districts, then such programs would be more desirable, assuming further cost-sharing is pursued. An interesting alternative would be to issue grants to air and water pollution control agencies which encompass a manageable segment of the problem such as water and air quality organizations which would in turn dispense these funds to industrial plants requesting assistance for studies to determine the most feasible way to achieve quality standards. The plants which are likely to face the largest abatement costs could be easily identified and feasibility studies could help identify least costly expenditures in order that these plants can achieve environmental quality standards. Also, additional information of annon-proprietary nature could help other plants facing similar problems. Furthermore, a subsidy of this kind would tend to increase the flow of human and physical resources into pollution abatement and create greater demand pressures for technological advance; this would undoubtedly lead to greater investment in private R&D. However, this alternative, although not without precedent, does tread close to the presently perceived line drawn between Government and industry responsibilities in the American economy. Assistance Based on Hardship The studies above clearly indicate the annual expenditures by manu- facturers for air and water pollution abatement are likely to be relatively small. ------- -30- However, some industrial plants may be forcfed to relocate or go out of business. This may be an unfortunate consequence of abatement enforcement. Such actions prolong the day when environmental quality standards are achieved. The enforcement process has attempted to recognize this problem and has allowed "hardship" cases a longer time period to comply with abatement actions. Assistance for hardship cases could provide the necessary incentive to abate earlier rather than later. From purely an equity standpoint, assistance could be considered for "hardship" plants. Such assistance could follow the pattern estab- lished for firms affected by downward adjustments in tariffs and quotas (e. g. , Trade Expansion Act and Canadian Automobile Trade Act), or as provided in the Economic Development Act, or as provided by the Small Business Administration Acts. This assistance could be in the form of low-interest loans, loan guarantees, lease guarantees, preferential Government purchase arrangements and other programs which already exist. Small Business Administration Program The program of the Small Business Administration (SBA) encompasses approximately 95% of all non-farm industry in the United States. Such pervasive coverage of American business occurs because of the broad mandate contained in SBA's legislation: A small business is defined as a company which is independently owned and operated and is not dominant in its field. For Defense set-aside purposes, American Motors is even defined as a small business. Among manufacturing industries, 94% of all firms are now classified as "small business!' (See Table XI). Moreover, over 90% of the firms in industries facing the greatest abate- ment costs -- foods, paper,, chemical, petroleum refining, and Primary Metals (Blast Furnaces) -- are classified as small businesses. The most useful SBA programs for hardship cases are Section 7A loans or loan guarantees and the lease guarantee program. Under Section 7A of the Small Business Act of 1958, SBA can make direct loans either by itself or in participation with banks and can guarantee loans made by banks. The agency has administratively set limits of $100, 000 on direct loans, $150, 000 on the SBA share of immediate participation loans, and $350, 000 on the guaranteed portion of loans made by private banks. Maximum term is 10 years except for that portion of the loan used for constructing, facilities on which the term may run up to 15 years. Interest is set at 5-1/2% on funds provided by SBA and up to 8% on funds provided by banks either as the bank share of immediate participation loans or as SBA guaranteed bank loans. ------- -31- Table XI Number and Proportion of All Manufacturing Firms Potentially Eligible to be Considered for Pollution Abatement Assistance under Programs of the Small Business Administration Standard Industrial Classification Industries Manufacturing Firms Potentially Eligible Estimated Percent of Number Total Number 20 Food and Kindred Products 31,409 96.3 22 Textile Mill Products 5,613 88.2 26 Paper and Allied Products 3,778 86.9 28 Chemicals and Allied Products 8,977 91.8 29 Petroleum Refining & Related Products 1,187 92.0 30 Rubber & Misc. Plastic Products 4,868 91.8 33 Primary Metal Industries, exclusive or SIC 3312 5,020 89.9 3312 Blast Furnaces (Including Coke Ovens), Steel Works & Rolling Mills 87 54.0 35 Machinery except Electrical 31,597 96.2 36 Electrical Machinery, Equipment and Supplies 8,209 91.0 37 Transportation Equipment 6,232 94.7 All Other Manufacturing Industries 160,532 * 95* TOTAL 267.509* 94* * Estimated Source: Unpublished Special Tabulation of the 1963 Census of Manufactures. Data made for the Small Business Administration by the Bureau of the Census. ------- -32- The major benefit to hardship firms would be guaranteed access to loans for purchasing pollution abatement equipment and facilities. Payment over 10 to 15 years greatly reduces the cash-flow burden that pollution abatement expenditures can cause. Hardship firms are frequently unable to secure such loans on their own, or even if they do receive a loan, they must pay it off within a year or two and at a high rate of interest. The extremely high cash flow requirement of these loans could cause firms to go out of business. The low interest, 5-1/2% on Government loans, offers an additional benefit. Even the loan guarantee program would reduce the interest rate facing hardship firms by a few percentage points and could be equivalent to a 5-15% subsidy. The Small Business Administration also administers a lease guarantee program which can be applied to the rental of pollution abatement equipment, both for the physical plant and land. Both the loan and lease programs provide considerable flexibility in meeting the capital requirements (including land) for pollution abatement actions affecting approximately 95% of industry. However, it does not include large firms that may have plants that are hit particularly hard by pollution abatement actions, especially in one-plant towns. Fortunately, assistance in these cases is potentially available from the Economic Development Administration programs. Economic Development Administration Programs The Economic Development Administration (EDA) can offer financial and technical assistance to any plant or firm, regardless of size, if pollution abatement actions should "tend to limit modernization, expansion or solvency of the facility. 11 Usually such a plant must be in a county which is designated as a "depressed area. 11 Nearly one-third of the land area in the United States is currently designated as depressed. EDA can also serve small areas. For example, as smkll an area as a set of census tracts within a city were designated as depressed because of the curtailment of work at the Brooklyn Naval Shipyard. In all areas, including those outside of "depressed areas, " EDA can pay 100% of the cost of technical studies for the purpose of identifying least-costly methods of abating pollution for plants in towns or sections of cities threatened by reduced economic activity. The only condition is that the pollution abatement actions against the affected plant can potentially or actually cause an increase in unemployment- Such a broad mandate allows adequate latitude for assisting any hardship plant which is otherwise economically viable except for the short-term burden of pollution abatement expenditures. ------- -33- Assistance Based on Bqrden Assistance can be offered to industry based solely on the burden to each plant or firm and not related to the ability of the firm to handle' the burden. It could be offered no matter whether it threatened the plant with relocation or failure or just requires an upward adjustment in product prices to cover the additional costs. The determination of relative burden could be based upon pollution abatement expenditures as a percentage of the Value-added for each plant. Once eligibility was determined, all assistance could be offered heavy burden cases. In addition, demonstration grants could be screened for use by the especially affected plants. There are* however, a number of administrative problems with this type of assistance which should be recognized. Assistance will require that there is some measurement of hardship and it is not clear over what period of time this period of hardship should be measured. For example, a new plant may have losses in its first year but by its fifth year be making a reasonable profit. The addition of pollution con- trols in its first year might be considered a. hardship whereas the addi- tion of pollution controls after the fifth year' would not be considered a hardship. However, assistance for a relatively short period of time is a desirable guidepost, say 5 years. Over the long run, the market- place should be the determinant of success or failure for each plant and firm. There is the question whether assistance should be used to,build a new plant. Inasmuch as entrepreneurs now gdnei'ally know the ground rules for pollution abatement, it is felt that new plants should be excluded from receiving assistance. Multi-plant firms present another problem. If Plant "A" of a multi- plant firm is shut down for pollution reasons and relocated, would this plant be eligible for pollution assistance? Also, if a plant is shut down in a multi-plant firm, is this of the same severity as a shutdown of a single-plant firm? The answer to this should depend in part on whether the multi-plant firm is located in a one plant town. Therefore, proper criteria and administrative discretion would have to be built into such an alternative. ------- -34- In some cases determining the least cost method of pollution abatement at each plant, a prerequisite 6f assessing the degree of hardship, might involve interference with the management prerogatives of the firm. For example, it might be possible to reduce the pollution problem in a plant by slightly altering the firm's product or its rate of output. Thus, pollution control is enhanced in a sulphuric acid plant if the rate of production is slowed. A coffee roasting plant which changes its coffee blending techniques might have significantly fewer pollution problems. Therefore, any program of assistance should consider the traditionally accepted prerogatives of management. At higher levels of assistance, or for selective assistance, eligibility for grants and loans of special certificates for tax benefits could be distributed through institutions that are required to manage air and water quality in each problem-shed area. This assistance could be used on the baaic of both the burden of pollution abatement expenditures and the need to reduce harmful waste loads. In this way, a subsidy could augment enforcement and help to minimize the total cost of pollution abatement. However, river basin and air-shed organizations are now in their infancy and need further development before a full scale prograni could be planned, even though it appears to be highly desirable. Performance Grants Grants for other forms of assistance could be offered on the basis of reduction in damaging waste loads through actual measurement. Such a subsidy could be based on the marginal effort to abate and thus would be highly efficient and facilitate enforcement. Moreover, this approach has the advantage of acting as a carrot. However, performance measures have not been perfected and therefore grants based on performance must wait for the future. With the current effort to improve pollution measuring devices, a performance program may be feasible within three years. The User Charge and the Effluent or Emission Charge Waste controls to reduce adverse effects on the environment may be produced most efficiently by charging the waste discharger for the damages his actions impose on the community or for the cost the community must incur to offset the effects of his waste disposal. The community in this sense is the (entire array of groups, entities, and persons affected by the waste disposers actions. ------- -35- The charges against the waste disposer must be determined either as a measure of actual damages caused or assigned against this dis- charger to produce a predetermined degree of control or reduction reflecting an environmental quality standard. In either instance the level of the charge is the critical factor and most difficult to determine. If the charge is too low, it will not constitute adequate inducement to reduce the wastes disposed and if the price is too high it will induce more control than is necessary and will.,be uneconomic in effect. Ex- perience through the use of such fees will holp reduce this uncertainty. Experimentation could be fruitfully pursued in a few river basins now. The term effluent or emission charge is used to refer to the price charged for direct disposal to the environment. The .term user charge refers to the price charged for waste treatment service provided in a treatment facility. The level of the effluent charge for direct disposal to the environment may be. based on the cost of reducing or treating the particular wastes in a treatment facility. The treatment facility would be designed and operated to modify the wastes sufficiently to meet the environmental standards. There is considerable experience with the user charge for industrial waste treatment service in collective public facilities. It has been successful in providing revenues to communities for replacement facilities, in encouraging sound industrial waste treatment practices, and in providing a businesslike way of managing a vital community service. Some pollution control experts see the establishment of regional waste treatment facilities for the acceptance of all wastes on a user charge basis as the appropriate solution to the water pollution control problem. The regional facility would be operated in accord with the hydrologic situation and environmental standards. However, waste treatment facilities on a collective basis are less applicable in the case of air pollution control. The only experience in America in this area has been the use of user charges by municipalities and other organizations handling wastes. Efflu- ent or emission charges have yet to be tried more extensively, although numerous task forces and studies have epecifically recommended their use on an experimental basis. So far, there is no experience with charges for air pollution control, although the advantage of using them is likely to be much greater. It is apparent that many difficulties are involved in setlihg and ad- ministering effluent charges, especially in the determination of the right price, surveillance and monitoring of performance when direct dis- charges or emissions are involved. In the air pollution situation, there is yet no opportunity to use the cost of treating emissions as a measure of the proper emission charge. Certainly it is wise to state for the third consecutive yearttftat effluent and emission fees should be tried in demonstration projects and experimental programs during 1968. Current legislative authority would permit such projects or programs. ------- - 36 - The thrust of this report has been to view subsidies for abatement in terms of other and possibly more effective expenditures. It is this axiom which supports the recommendation that the Secretary of Health, Education and Welfare and the Secretary of Interior assess the effective- ness of the presently available abatement assistance. Performance grants, emission charges and effluent fees are not now entirely feasible and must await the development of adequate institutions, improved moni- toring methods, and better pollution damage estimates. The development of new institutions for the administration of abatement can contribute significantly to efficient pollution abatement. Therefore, funds should be set aside to support experimental projects in this area. Until these and other developments aire forthcoming, cost-sharing should be limited to those cases experiencing hardship. ------- -37- Members of the Working Committee on Economic Incentives Aim, Alvin Li , Bureau of the Budget Brannon, Gerard M. , Treasury- Carlson, Jack W. , Chairman of the Working Committee and the Parent Committee, Council of Economic Advisers Caulfield, Henry, Water Resources Council Dworsky, Leonard, Office of Science and Technology Elkins, Charles L. , Bureau of the Budget Flannery, James, Department of the Interior Frankel, Richard, Resources for the Future Gerhardt, Paul, Health, Education and Welfare Smith, Edward, Department of Commerce Wilson, Douglas, Health, Education, and Welfare ------- |