UNITED STATES
ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY
A FRAMEWORK FOR THE
ECONOMIC ASSESSMENT OF
ECOLOGICAL BENEFITS
February 1, 2002
     Acknowledgements

-------
The preparation of A Framework for Ecological Benefits Assessment (henceforth Framework) was
managed under the direction of the Social Sciences Discussion Workgroup, a working group under the
Science Policy Council. Initial work on the Framework began in 1996 and concluded in 2001.

The principle managers of the Framework workgroup were Betsy Southerland and Mary Ellen Weber.
The workgroup consists of staff economists and ecologists from program and regional offices across the
Agency. The workgroup was originally chaired by John D. Harris and then by Lynne Blake-Hedges.
Lynne Blake-Hedges was responsible for final preparation of text with valuable assistance from Randy
Bruins, Matt Heberling, and Anne Sergeant.  Contributors to the development of the content and focus of
the document include Ghulam Ali, Erik Beck, Ed Bender, Richard Healy, Rich lovanna, Virginia Kibler,
Robert Lee II, Bill O'Neil, Neil Patel, Rosalina Rodriguez, Elliot Rosenberg, Christine Ruf, and Will
Wheeler.

In addition to EPA staff, a number of contractors provided administrative support and developed key
materials used as technical assistance in preparation of the Framework. They include Carolyn Russell,
Kevin Blake, and Margaret McVey of ICF, Incorporated.

Reviews of document drafts were completed by Erik Beck, Ed Bender, Robert Perciasepe, Will Wheeler,
Joan P. Baker, Jeri-Anne Garl, John Miller, Dan Phalen and Shari Stevens of EPA; as well as Ed
Whitelaw, University of Oregon; Paul Courant, University of Michigan; Ernie Niemi, ECONorthwest;
Jeffrey Lazo, Penn State University;  James Shortle, and Penn State University. A final peer review was
conducted in 1998. Critical review and comment provided by Paul Jacobson, Langhei Ecology LLC and
John Hopkins University, Barbara Kanninen, University of Minnesota, Greg Poe, Cornell, and Jonathan
Rubin, University of Maine.

-------
  A FRAMEWORK FOR THE ECONOMIC
ASSESSMENT OF ECOLOGICAL BENEFITS
                 Prepared for

        Ecological Benefit Assessment Workgroup
           Social Sciences Discussion Group
              Science Policy Council
          U.S. Environmental Protection Agency
               February 1, 2002

-------

-------
                                TABLE OF CONTENTS
Acknowledgements  	iv

1.0    Introduction	1
       1.1    Background  	1
       1.2    Purpose and Scope	1
       1.3    Organization of this Document 	4

2.0    A Proposed Framework	5
       2.1    Overview	5
       2.2    Planning	7
       2.3    Problem  Formulation - Initial Coordination
                            	9
             2.3.1   Problem Formulation	9
             2.3.2   Initial Coordination  	10
       2.4    Linking Endpoints During Problem Formulation
              	13
             2.4.1 Conceptual Model of a Cascade of Ecological Effects	13
             2.4.2   Identifying Preliminary Economic Endpoints
                     	15
             2.4.3   Identifying and Defining Linkages
                     	16
       2.5    Problem Formulation - Prioritizing Endpoints and Selecting Valuation Techniques
              	19
             2.5.1   Prioritization Criteria	19
             2.5.2   Monetized, Quantitative, and Qualitative Assessments
                     	21
       2.6    Problem Formulation - Ensuring Analytical and Data Compatibility in the
             Analysis Plans
              	23
             2.6.1   Establishing the Baseline and Alternative Scenarios
                     	23
             2.6.2   Measuring and Modeling Linkages
                     	24
             2.6.3   Matching Spatial Scales
                     	25
             2.6.4   Matching Temporal Scales  	26
             2.6.5   Data Limitations and Uncertainty
                     	26
       2.7    Conducting the Assessments	27
             2.7.1   Ecological Risk/Benefit Assessment	27
             2.7.2   Qualitative and Quantitative Economic Assessment	28
       2.8    Characterizing and Presenting Results  	29
       2.9    Concluding Remarks	30
                                                                                 Page i

-------
       References and Further Reading 	31

3.0    Important Principles of Ecology and Ecological Assessment  	34
       3.1    Defining Ecosystem and Other Levels of Ecological Organization  	34
             3.1.1   Definitions	34
             3.1.2   Levels of Biological Organization	35
             3.1.3   Interactions Within Ecosystems	35
       3.2    Understanding Ecosystem Structure and Function  	39
       3.3    Valued Ecological Entities	43
             3.3.1   Definitions	43
             3.3.2   Identifying Valued Ecological Entities 	44
             3.3.3   Neglected  Benefits	46
       3.4    Types of Ecological Assessments 	50
             3.4.1   Assessment Models	50
             3.4.2   Standardized Approaches to Ecological Assessments	53

4.0    Ecological Risk/Benefit Assessment  	59
       4.1    Overview of EPA's Guidelines for Ecological Risk Assessment	59
       4.2    Phase I:  Problem Formulation	61
             4.2.1   Conceptual Model  	63
             4.2.2   Assessment Endpoints	66
       4.3    Phase II: Analysis Phase	71
       4.4    Phase III: Risk/Benefit Characterization  	82

5.0    Background Theory on Valuing Changes to Ecological Resources 	86
       5.1    Welfare Economics and the Value of an Ecological Change 	86
       5.2    Measuring the Benefits of Improvements to Ecological Resources - The Concept
             of Willingness-To-Pay	87
       5.3    How Economic Benefits of Improvements to Ecological Resources are Realized
              	88
       5.4    Estimating Willingness-to-Pay  	89

6.0    Economic Assessment of Ecological Benefits	91
       6.1    Components of an Economic Assessment of Ecological Benefits  	91
             6.1.1   Identify and Prioritize Economic Benefit Endpoints	92
             6.1.2   Describe and Quantify Changes to the Economic Benefit Endpoints  ... 93
             6.1.3   Estimate the Value  of the Changes 	93
             6.1.4   Summarize and Present the Results	94
       6.2    Identifying the Service Flows and Other Values Provided
                    by an Ecological  Resource	96
             6.2.1   Direct, Market Uses	99
             6.2.2   Direct Non-Market Uses  	101
             6.2.3   Indirect, Non-Market Uses  	103
             6.2.4   Non-Market, Non-Use Values	105
       6.3    Approaches to Measuring Resource Values  	107
             6.3.1   Market Price and Supply/Demand Relationships  	112
             6.3.2   Market-Based Valuation Approaches 	115

                                                                                 Page ii

-------
             6.3.3  Travel Cost Methodologies  	121
             6.3.4  Random Utility Model	125
             6.3.5  Hedonic Price and Hedonic Wage Methodologies  	128
             6.3.6  Contingent Valuation	134
             6.3.7  Combining Contingent Valuation with Other Approaches: Contingent
                    Activity  	143
             6.3.8  Conjoint Analysis and Contingent Ranking 	145
             6.3.9  Benefits Transfer	150

7.0    Issues Affecting the Economic Valuation of Ecological Benefits	155
       7.1    Uncertainty and Variability	155
       7.2    Discounting  	156
       7.3    Distributional and Equity Analyses	156

8.0    References  	158
       8.1    Ecological References and Further Reading	158
       8.2    Economic References and Further Reading	168
                                                                                 Page iii

-------
                                   Acknowledgements
The preparation of A Framework for Ecological Benefits Assessment (henceforth Framework) was
managed under the direction of the Social Sciences Discussion Workgroup, a working group under the
Science Policy Council. Initial work on the Framework began in 1996 and concluded in 2001.

The principle managers of the Framework workgroup were Betsy Southerland and Mary Ellen Weber.
The workgroup consists of staff economists and ecologists from program and regional offices across the
Agency. The workgroup was originally chaired by John D. Harris and then by Lynne Blake-Hedges.
Lynne Blake-Hedges was responsible for final preparation of text with valuable assistance from Randy
Bruins, Matt Heberling, and Anne Sergeant.  Contributors to the development of the content and focus of
the document include Ghulam Ali, Erik Beck, Ed Bender, Richard Healy, Rich lovanna, Virginia Kibler,
Robert Lee II, Bill O'Neil, Neil Patel, Rosalina Rodriguez, Elliot Rosenberg, Christine Ruf, and Will
Wheeler.

In addition to EPA staff, a number of contractors provided administrative support and developed key
materials used as technical assistance in preparation of the Framework. They include Carolyn Russell,
Kevin Blake, and Margaret  McVey of ICF, Incorporated.

Reviews of document drafts were completed by Erik Beck, Ed Bender, Robert Perciasepe, Will Wheeler,
Joan P. Baker, Jeri-Anne Garl, John Miller, Dan Phalen and Shari Stevens of EPA; as well as Ed
Whitelaw, University of Oregon; Paul Courant, University of Michigan; Ernie Niemi, ECONorthwest;
Jeffrey Lazo, Penn State University; James Shortle, and Penn State University. A final peer review was
conducted in 1998. Critical review and comment provided by Paul Jacobson, Langhei Ecology LLC and
John Hopkins University, Barbara Kanninen, University of Minnesota, Greg Poe, Cornell, and Jonathan
Rubin, University of Maine.
                                                                                       Page iv

-------
1.0   INTRODUCTION
1.1    BACKGROUND

The Social Sciences Discussion Group (SSDG), convened under the auspices of the EPA
Science Policy Council, was initiated to address issues related to the conduct of economic and
other social science analyses at EPA.  One of their efforts focused on improving the Agency's
ability to conduct economic benefit analyses for regulatory cost-benefit or relative benefit
assessments. The SSDG identified a need to "improve the Agency's ability to quantify, and,
where possible, monetize ecological benefits, including quality of life." A workgroup
representing all major EPA programs and environmental media was established to meet that
charge.

The workgroup began by surveying EPA offices for completed or ongoing analyses of ecological
benefits to determine the current state  of the practice within EPA. During this exercise, the
workgroup identified the need for a common approach to analyzing ecological benefits and a
better understanding of both the scientific and economic techniques used in these analyses.

1.2    PURPOSE AND SCOPE

This document represents a joint effort of ecologists and economists. This document is intended
to address the two needs identified above by (1) proposing a common framework for the
economic analysis of ecological benefits and (2) discussing the elements of ecological risk
assessment and economic benefit analysis. In addition, this document is intended to:

•      Promote greater coordination between  ecologists and economists working on such
       efforts;

•      Provide an understanding of the approaches and techniques currently in use;

•      Suggest additional sources of information; and

•      Provide a starting point for individuals who need to assign economic values to changes in
       ecosystems that have or might  result from human activities.

This document is intended to provide general information to EPA staff and others who are
interested in the concepts and techniques used to assess and quantify ecological effects of an
environmental decision and to monetize ecological impacts and benefits. An important aspect of
the document is an introduction of a framework for collaboration between economists and
ecologists. The framework presented is not intended as Agency guidance and should not be
considered to be promoting any particular benefits methodology.

The document is not designed to be either a "cookbook" or a "how to" manual — it does not
provide a step-by-step guidance on the application of specific techniques. Because this
document is a framework for estimating the economic value of ecological benefits, it also does
                                                                                Page 1

-------
not address other possible effects of an action or other perspectives.  Specifically, this document
does not
              discuss non-ecological effects, such as human health impacts or socio-economic
effects (e.g., employment, local revenue, growth).

The Framework presented in this document represents one part of a larger process of
environmental decisionmaking at EPA, as illustrated by the white box with a double-line border
in Exhibit 1.  The goal of the Framework is to provide a structure for conducting benefits
assessments for the purpose of informing risk management decisions and to meet risk
management objectives.  It is most applicable for determining, as part of a benefit cost analysis,
the ecological benefits of policies or regulatory actions commonly undertaken by governmental
agencies such as the EPA.  Other types of analyses that might be conducted to inform a decision,
such as human risk assessment, environmental justice assessments, and other types of economic
assessments, are beyond the scope of this document, but may be included in the decisionmaking
process.  Discussion of other types of economic analyses  can be found in EPA's (2000)
Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses. Other activities included in environmental
decisionmaking, such as monitoring and program evaluation, also are not addressed in this
Framework.

For an economic analysis of ecological benefits of a decision to be conducted, an assessment of
the ecological changes that might result from that decision is needed. In essence, an ecological
risk assessment is required, where both beneficial changes as well as potentially adverse changes
(the usual implication of the word "risk" in many risk assessment contexts) in ecological
endpoints, are evaluated. We have therefore chosen to develop a framework for the economic
evaluation of ecological  benefits around the framework in EPA's (1998) Ecological Risk
Assessment Guidelines, which consists of planning, problem formulation, analysis of stresses and
effects, and risk characterization.

The Framework proposed in this document identifies the  major points in the ecological and
economic assessment processes where coordination between the two assessments is needed.
This Framework is intended to provide a starting point for approaching such analyses; it does not
prescribe a particular method of research  or interaction.  An  important aspect of the Framework
is the recognition that ecological risk assessment and economic benefits assessment are distinct
disciplines.  It focuses on the phases of the respective assessment processes during which
communication and coordination between ecologists and  economists are needed to ensure an
adequate benefits assessment.  While it has been assembled based on the experience and
judgment of EPA environmental economists and ecological risk assessors, this Framework per se
has not undergone testing - such as through a program of case studies.

Efforts to manage ecological resources using a place-based (or community-based) approach can
differ from a government agency-based approach and may require additional tools not described
in this document. Place-based environmental  management situations may be characterized by
multiple parties; varied or competing objectives; weak or decentralized authorities; and a broad
range of potential actions which analyses must seek to narrow and define. Economic approaches
involving scenario simulation, multiple agents, or multiple objectives, as well as conventional
valuation approaches, may be useful. An EPA, Office of Research and Development effort to
                                                                                  Page 2

-------
integrate place-based ecological risk assessment and economics, which explores the utility of a
range of economic tools, is underway (U.S. EPA, 2000b). In addition, an EPA and Science
                                                                                 Page 3

-------
                                         Exhibit 1
                         Environmental Decisionmaking Process
Planning
Dialogue among Environmental Decisionmakers/Risk Managers..
Stakeholders., Risk Assessors,, Economists.. Sociologists., and others to
decide which analyses are needed and the scope of those analyses.
A
^

ws
u
C
Economic Assessment of Ecological Be


Ecological RiskAssessment



t
r



Human Health RiskAssessment

i




Other Economic Analyses of Costs
and Benefits




Other Assessments as Needed

F
Communicating Results to Environmental Uecisionmaker

A
1
k
T
Environmental Management Decisions and
Coiimiunicating Results to Interested Parties



^ 	



*
As needed, Acquire Data, Iterate Process,
Monitor Re suits
*

          Note: This Framework focuses only on the economic assessment of ecological benefits
          depicted in the clear box with a double outline.
Advisory Board workshop exploring the potential contribution of non-economic approaches to
ecological valuation, including approaches from psychology, anthropology and decision science,
occurred in May 2001 and will be followed by a report.
                                                                                     Page 4

-------
1.3    ORGANIZATION OF THIS DOCUMENT

The remainder of this document is organized in seven sections.

Chapter 2:   The Framework: Provides an overview of the Framework and a description of
             each of its components, emphasizing the points of coordination between the
             ecological risk assessment team and the economic assessment team.

Chapter 3:   Important Principles of Ecology and Ecological Assessments: Defines
             ecosystems  and biological levels of organization. Describes the interactive nature
             of ecosystems and cascading effects.  Provides an overview of prospective and
             retrospective assessments.

Chapter 4:   The Ecological Risk Assessment Process: Provides an overview of EPA's
             Framework and guidelines for ecological risk assessment, emphasizing where
             coordination with the economists is needed to ensure an adequate economic
             assessment of possible ecological changes.

Chapter 5:   Background Theory on Valuing Changes to Ecological Resources: Provides
             an introduction to how economists  define the value of ecological resources and
             the theoretical basis for estimating  changes in these values to measure economic
             benefits.

Chapter 6:   Economic Assessment of Ecological Benefits: Provides an overview of the
             economic assessment of ecological benefits, including detailed information on the
             types of benefits that might be identified and the techniques available for valuing
             changes.

Chapter 7:   Issues: Discusses some additional issues relevant to the economic analysis of
             ecological benefits, including uncertainty, discounting, aggregation, and equity.

Chapter 8:   References: Provides a complete listing of the materials used to develop the
             Framework as well as suggested readings for additional information.
References and Further Reading

U.S. EPA. 1998. Guidelines for Ecological Risk Assessment. Risk Assessment Forum.
EPA/630/R-95/002F.

U.S. EPA. 2000a. Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses.  Office of the Administrator.
EPA240-R-00-003. September.

U.S. EPA. 2000b. Research Plan for Integrating Ecological Risk Assessment and Economics in
Place-Based Decision Making. NCEA-C-0633.  National Center for Environmental Assessment,
Office of Research and Development, Washington, DC.


                                                                               Page 5

-------
2.0  A PROPOSED FRAMEWORK
This section describes a proposed framework for the economic assessment of ecological benefits.
It describes the relationship between ecological and economic analyses, identifying many of the
points of interdisciplinary coordination between the ecological risk assessment team and the
economic analysts. This chapter provides an overview of this Framework (Section 2.1) and a
discussion of the key phases and elements of the process, including the planning phase (Section
2.2), several elements of the problem formulation phase (Sections 2.3 through 2.6), conducting
the analyses (Section 2.7), and characterizing and presenting results (Section 2.8).

2.1    OVERVIEW

The proposed Framework describes a process by which the ecological risk assessors and
economic analysts conduct and coordinate their assessments as recommended by recent EPA
guidance.  (See U.S. EPA, 1997; 2001.) Interdisciplinary coordination promotes:

•      Development of better information for risk managers;

•      Greater utility of ecological assessments for economic assessment of ecological benefits;

•      Greater relevance of economic assessments to ecological resource issues; and

•      Timely and streamlined collection of necessary data.

Exhibit 2 illustrates this Framework within the context of the larger environmental
decisionmaking process. While this Framework follows the general phases outlined in EPA's
(1998) Guidelines for Ecological Risk Assessment.,  it focuses  on the coordination between the
ecologists and economists during those phases.  EPA's ecological risk assessment process can
readily be adapted to an ecological  benefits assessment and consists of a problem formulation
phase, analysis phase, and risk characterization phase (U.S. EPA,  1998). The steps of the
economic benefits analysis, as identified in EPA's (2000) Guidelines for Preparing Economic
Analyses., are matched with the ecological risk/benefit assessment process. The economic
benefits assessment consists of identifying the potentially affected benefit endpoints, quantifying
the significant changes to these endpoints, and estimating the economic value of those changes.

As a precursor to conducting an economic assessment of ecological benefits, a planning step
occurs where risk managers, stakeholders, risk assessors, economists, and other parties each
share their perspectives on the problem to help guide planning of goals, scope, and resources for
the assessment.  Planning for and beginning an economic benefit analysis simultaneously with
the ecological benefit assessment allows for the coordination  called for by the Framework and
can greatly improve the economic assessment of ecological benefits.  The majority of the
interdisciplinary coordination between the ecological risk assessors and the economic analysts
occurs during the planning and problem formulation phases and again at the end, in the
                                                                                 Page 6

-------
                                       Exhibit 2
             A Framework for Economic Assessments of Ecological Benefits
                                  Planning
      Dialogue among Risk Managers, Stakeholders, Risk Assessors, and Others
         Economic Assessment of Ecological Benefits
      Ecological Assessment        Economic Assessment
       Problem Formulation
Problem Formulation
                    Conceptual Model
                   Endpoints - Linkages
                  Analytic Compatibility
                                    Analysis Plan
            Ecological
             Analyses
       Exposure     Effects
       Risk Characterization
  Economic Analyses

       Monetary
      Quantitative
      Qualitative
                       Present Results
     Communicating Results to Risk Manager/Environmental Decisionmaker
                          Risk Management and
                Communicating Results to Interested Parties
                                                o
                                                hQ
ro
a
ro
"d
3
o
O)
                                                                               8.
                                                                               (-4-
                                                                               o
presentation of the results.  The planning and problem formulation steps of the economic
assessment of ecological benefits include the following:

       During the planning phase of the overall assessment, the planning team agrees on the
       scope of the proposed action, the risk management objectives, the management
       alternatives and policy options that will be explored by the assessments, the types of
       studies and activities that will occur as part of each assessment, and the basic information
                                                                                 Page 7

-------
       required to support each of those studies and activities (Section 2.2).  This document only
       discusses planning as related to the economic assessment of ecological benefits.

       At the beginning of problem formulation, ecologists and economists discuss the
       information agreed to during the planning phase as it relates to their analyses and begin
       the design of their respective conceptual models (Section 2.3).

•      After identifying the direct and possible indirect ecological changes that might result
       from options under assessment, economists and ecologists work together to link
       ecological changes to economic endpoints (Section 2.4).

       Based on the resources available for the assessment and other appropriate criteria,
       ecologists and economists prioritize the assessment endpoints to identify a subset for
       quantitative analysis (Section 2.5).

•      As ecologists and economists develop their assessment plans, they confer on several
       issues to ensure that the ecological assessment and the economic benefit analysis are
       analytically compatible before finalizing their assessment plans at the end of problem
       formulation (Section 2.6).

       The ecological risk assessment team conducts its assessment.   Using results from the
       ecological risk assessment, economists  complete their assessment of the economic
       benefits of the ecological changes (Section 2.7).

•      Both groups characterize and present the results of their assessments (Section 2.8).  The
       ecological risk assessment team might also present results for some questions unrelated
       to the economic analysis (e.g., which species might serve best as indicators for future
       monitoring of ecological changes).

Because portions of the ecological risk/benefit assessment and economic analysis of the
ecological changes will occur simultaneously, along with any other studies included in the
overall assessment, certain parts of the process outlined in this Framework might be repeated
until the information is sufficiently precise to be of use in decisionmaking.

2.2    PLANNING

Environmental decisionmaking begins with a planning step.  The goal of planning is to identify
the context of the environmental decision, the risk management objectives, the options under
assessment, the individuals involved, the types of analyses that are needed, what resources are
available, and to resolve other questions concerning scope and process. Typically, an ecological
risk management objective has an entity, an attribute, and a desired state or direction of
preference. The  risk management objective helps to focus the assessments on risks that are
susceptible to management. The decisionmakers or risk managers meet with staff who can
represent the disciplines that might be required, including toxicologists, sociologists, economists,
ecologists, risk assessors, engineers, as well as potentially interested or affected parties.  The
assessment teams might include representatives of Federal, State, local, and tribal governments,
                                                                                    PageS

-------
commercial, industrial, and private organizations, leaders of constituency groups, and other
sectors of the public.

Several types of questions may be addressed during the planning phase:

       What kind of decision is involved (e.g., siting a facility; regulation development)?
•      Who is involved in decisionmaking (i.e., who are the risk managers)?
•      Who are the stakeholders (those affected and those who are needed to help define the
       value of ecological benefits)?
•      What analyses will be required (e.g., socioeconomic, human health, ecological)?

Products of planning dialogues can include several types of information:

       The type of management goals at issue (e.g., benefits exceed costs, restore striped bass
       population in the Potomac to its 1940 level);
•      The exact nature and timing of the decisions to be made and who will make them;
•      The analyses to be performed and which analyses must be coordinated;
•      Agreement on  scope,  complexity, and focus of the assessments, including the expected
       output; and
       The timeline and technical and financial support available to conduct the assessments.

Depending on the context, decision, management goals, and other attributes of the decision at
hand, one or more of several  different types of analyses might be called for, including human
health risk assessment, ecological risk assessment,  economic assessment of health risks,
economic assessment of ecological changes, environmental equity or justice, and others (Exhibit
1).  This Framework addresses only the economic assessment of ecological benefits, and thus
focuses on a subset of the possible analyses that might be conducted during the environmental
decisionmaking process.

During planning, the economists, ecologists, toxicologists, and staff representing other involved
disciplines can contribute to a definition of the scope of the problem and alternatives to be
considered.  For example, economic analysts might provide preliminary information from market
research efforts that indicate what chemicals/products are being manufactured and used and in
what amounts. Producers and consumers and chemical uses can be identified. Risk assessors
might use this information to determine where (geographically) exposures might take place, the
magnitude and frequency  of exposure (how chemicals/products are used), and exposed
populations (both human and ecological).

Economic analysts might  also provide insights on economically feasible substitutes that might be
used if a chemical or product is no longer available, projecting potential market shares and
production and use volumes.  Socioeconomic information on the conditions of affected
communities and/or populations can provide insight as to what the concerns and potential risk
management alternatives are  for a particular community. Economic factors, in addition to others
such as political and cultural  factors, also come into play when identifying feasible risk
management alternatives.
                                                                                   Page 9

-------
Ecologists can provide information on likely direct and indirect ecological impacts, sensitive
ecosystems or receptors, and likely spatial and temporal scales over which ecological changes
might be expressed.  With information on environmental persistence and bioaccumulation
potential for chemicals, ecologists can evaluate whether food-chain analyses might be important
to the assessment. They also can provide initial judgments on likely magnitude, severity, and
reversibility of anticipated effects.

By the completion of the planning step, agreements have been made about several aspects of the
assessment: (1) the management goals, (2) the range of management options that the ecological
and economic analyses are intended to support, (3) characterization of the decisions to be made
given the management goals, (4) the focus, scope, and complexity of the assessments, and (5)
resources available to conduct the assessment. At a general level, there must be agreement on
the spatial  and temporal scale of the assessments.  At this point, the groups that will need to
coordinate with each other also are identified.

2.3   PROBLEM FORMULATION - INITIAL COORDINATION

2.3.1 Problem Formulation

Once planning is complete, the risk and economic assessments can begin. In its (1998)
Guidelines for Ecological Risk Assessment, EPA describes problem formulation as the first
phase of an ecological risk assessment. The same principles described in those Guidelines can
apply to problem formulation phase for an economic assessment.  Problem formulation in this
Framework includes integrating available information, selecting ecological and economic
assessment endpoints, developing of a conceptual model linking the proposed actions to
ecological and economic endpoints, and developing analysis plans for the ecological and
economic benefit assessments (Exhibit 3).
                                                                                Page 10

-------
                                        Exhibit 3
          Problem Formulation for Economic Assessment of Ecological Benefits
                               Integrate Available Information
            Ecological D
     —> Develop Conceptual Models  •*—


Identify Endpoints and Linkages Between Them
EconomicD
                     Prioritize Endpoints and Select Valuation Techniques
                                              I
                  Develop Analysis Plans, Ensuring Analytical Compatibility
             Ecological Analysis Plan
                                 Economic Analysis Plan
This document focuses on four parts of the problem formulation phase: (1) initial coordination in
defining the problem; (2) developing the conceptual models that identify linkages between
ecological and economic endpoints; (3) prioritizing endpoints for quantitative and qualitative
assessment, and (4) ensuring analytic compatibility between the ecological risk and economic
assessment plans.  Exhibit 4 provides a detailed illustration of the problem formulation phase.
                        Questions Asked During Problem Formulation

     What laws already protect what entities?
     What are the policy considerations (law, corporate stewardship, societal concerns, intergenerational
     equity)?
     What is the nature of the problem?
     What is the context of the assessment?
     What is the likely scale of the assessment in time and space?
     What is the starting information like?
     Develop a conceptual model of the problem, context, scale, then:
     -What are the most obvious assessment endpoints (i.e., relevance to management goals)?
     -What additional endpoints are ecologically and socially relevant (e.g., laws can be good indicators of
     societal values) or important to stakeholders?
2.3.2  Initial Coordination
                                                                                      Page 11

-------
During the preliminary dialogues among the risk managers, risk assessors, economic analysts,
and stakeholders in the planning stage, the ecological assessors and economic analysts will have
begun to formulate ideas about the tasks ahead of them. Fundamental to beginning problem
formulation is a clear description of the environmental decision at hand, the options under
evaluation, the types of actions, and the initial changes those actions would cause in the abiotic
environment (e.g., land use, water flow, chemical concentrations). The ecologists will begin to
formulate  an understanding of the proposed options and the types of ecosystem structures and
services that might be affected by those options; the economists will develop some ideas as to
the most obvious economic benefits that might accrue. The discussions initiated during the
planning stage between ecologists and economists to define the scope of the overall assessment
will continue throughout the problem formulation process. The sharing of information and ideas
can be particularly helpful in developing comprehensive conceptual models.

For both the ecological and economic assessments, problem formulation begins by integrating
the information from the initial discussions of the problem, including the context of the
assessment, its goals and constraints, the decisions to be made, and which stakeholders are
involved.  Separate ecological and economic assessment teams are assembled to include the
required areas of expertise and also possibly to include stakeholder representatives.  Careful
consideration about who will participate and how they will participate is best done up front.
                                                                                  Page 12

-------
                                          Exhibit 4
                                   Problem Formulation
                Ecologists
                                                                     Economists
Establish Preliminary Conceptual Model
1.  From planning: context, goals, constraints,
decisions, decisionmakers, stakeholders
2.  Integrate available information
3.  Develop conceptual model linking
action/source (rectangle) to direct ecological
effects (ovals) and indirect ecological effects
(circles)
Establish Preliminary Economic Model
1.  From planning: context, goals, constraints,
decisions, decisionmakers, stakeholders
2.  Integrate available information
3.  Identify likely economic benefit endpoints in
different categories (squares) and develop
conceptual model
Direct Market
Use
Indirect Non-
Market Use
D
D
Direct Non-
Market Use D
Non-Use Value
D
         Identify Linkages between Ecological Change and Economic Benefit Endpoints
            Prioritize Ecological Endpoints  O O   Prioritize Economic Endpoints D
                           Agree to Assessment Endpoints for Analysis
     Develop Preliminary Analysis Plan
For assessment endpoints, develop measures;
models; characteristics of ecosystems; state
variables; spatial and temporal boundaries
         Design Approach for Assessment
 Specify technique(s) for valuing changes to
 selected benefit endpoints; select preliminary time
 horizon; discounting; etc.
                    Ensure Analytical Compatibility and Finalize Analysis Plans
             1. Adjust time horizon and time steps of both assessments to match as possible
             2. Adjust spatial extent and resolution of assessment to match as possible
             3. Specify treatment and analyses of uncertainty
                                                                                               Page 13

-------
2.4    LINKING ENDPOINTS DURING
       PROBLEM FORMULATION
           What Is An Endpoint?

Endpoints differ by discipline. Ecological
assessment endpoints are explicit descriptions
of the actual environmental attribute that is
expected to change in response to an action.
Ecological assessment endpoints are
operationally defined by an ecological entity
and its attributes. Changes to ecological
assessment endpoints are estimated from
analyses of both direct and indirect effects of
the action  and in the context of a benefits
assessment, are used to estimate changes in the
economic  benefit endpoints. Economic benefit
endpoints  are the goods or services provided or
supported  by the ecological resource, directly
or indirectly, that have economic value (see
Section 5.3) to society,  such as recreational
fishing.. Changes in the economic benefit
endpoints  are used to assess the economic
value of the action under study.
After the initial coordination, each
assessment team begins to develop an
explicit conceptual model of their part of
the analysis. The ecologists begin by
tracing the consequences of the proposed
actions from the sources through the initial
changes produced in the physical and
chemical characteristics of the
environment, direct effects on ecological
entities, and then the cascade of secondary
ecological effects that might follow.

The economic benefit assessment is based
on the premise that actions affecting the
state of an ecological resource, measured
in terms of changes to the ecological
assessment endpoints, will result in
changes to the goods  and services provided
by that resource (i.e.,  changes to the
economic benefit endpoints). Because of
this connection, economists need to work
with ecologists and other scientists in
determining what economic benefit endpoints are likely to be affected and estimating the
magnitude of those effects. By working with economists to define the economic benefit
endpoints, ecologists  can help ensure that ecologically significant but less obvious or less direct
effects are not overlooked by the economic benefit analysis.  Furthermore, as ecologists gain a
better understanding of the objectives and process of the economic benefit analysis, they might
be able to provide information and data that are better suited to the needs of the economist.

2.4.1 Conceptual  Model of a Cascade of Ecological Effects

The ecologist outlines ecological changes that might result from one or more decisions and
actions. Exhibit 5 illustrates a simple, preliminary conceptual model that might be drawn up to
depict possible ecological benefits of improving local septic  systems, one  of many possible risk
management actions.  The diagram in Exhibit 5 is a substantial oversimplification of a
conceptual model for purposes of illustration only. For additional examples and explanation of
the development of conceptual models for ecological risk assessments, see Chapter 4.

The conceptual model traces the sequence of changes from the initial direct effect of reduced
nutrient loading to  surface waters to the  consequences of that effect, here described as reduced
eutrophication  (i.e., nutrient enrichment) of local waters, which in turn would lead to improved
                                                                                 Page 14

-------
                        Exhibit 5
Diagram Linking Action to Cascade of Ecological Effects
                Improved Local Septic Systems
                              I
                   Reduced Nutrient Loading
                              I
            Reduced Eutrophication in Local Waters
      Improved Aquatic
           Habitat
                    Improved Wetland
                  Function and Structure
             I
       Increased Macro-
     invertebrate Abundance
             I
                     Improved Water
                        Filtration
          Increased
        Fish/Shellfish
         Populations
aquatic habitat for fish and
shellfish populations, and that, in
turn, might support larger
populations of breeding and
migratory shorebirds.  The
reduced eutrophication also
would be expected to improve
the condition and areal extent
of wetland vegetation and the
ability of that vegetation to
filter sediments, nutrients, and
contaminants out  of the water
before the water reaches rivers
and lakes.

The cascade of indirect effects
and interactions among the
affected entities, which is
characteristic of ecosystems,
can be difficult for economists
and non-ecologists to envision.
As the ecological  risk
assessment team develops their
conceptual model, they should
meet frequently with the
economic analysts to explain
the ecological relationships
and interactions represented by
the conceptual model.
Communicating with
economists during the process
of developing the ecological conceptual model, starting with the most simple preliminary model,
will greatly improve economists' understanding of the ecological assessment and help
economists to define appropriate economic benefit endpoints.

One difference between the ecological conceptual models for risk assessments designed to
identify environmental concentrations of concern or to  set cleanup levels and those conducted to
support economic analyses deserves note here.  A conceptual model used to design an ecological
risk assessment to establish environmental concentrations of concern or cleanup levels at a
specific site often focuses on the most sensitive and exposed (i.e., vulnerable) receptors or
processes  in the ecosystem at the site.  The goal is to identify contaminant concentrations in
environmental media that are unlikely to cause adverse ecological effects. In Exhibit 5, the most
vulnerable endpoint might be  shellfish populations. To document an environmental
concentration of concern, for example, an ecological risk assessment might be able to stop there,
and consider only increased shellfish populations as a goal. A conceptual model that will be
linked to an economic assessment of ecological benefits should attempt to identify all of the
direct and indirect effects of an environmental decision. The additional ecological effects
  Increased
Migratory Bird
Visitation Rate
 Increased
Shore Bird
Population
Improved
  Water
 Quality
                                                  Page 15

-------
depicted in Exhibit 5 are added to allow the economic analysis to capture a more complete
spectrum of ecological benefits.

When developing a conceptual model to support an economic assessment of ecological benefits,
the ecologists should also consider the possibility for adverse effects.  What is beneficial for one
species can be detrimental to another, as has sometimes occurred when land is managed for the
benefit of a single species (e.g., game species such as deer).

2.4.2  Identifying Preliminary Economic Endpoints

EPA primarily relies on an effect-by-effect approach for estimating the benefits of a policy
option (U.S. EPA, 2000a). This approach involves identifying the major beneficial effects of an
action (e.g., various types of improvements to activities or functions of ecological resources),
assessing the economic value of each of these improvements independently, and summing up the
individual values to provide an estimate of the total benefits. Identifying the major beneficial
effects that will be examined in detail in the benefit analysis involves several steps. Before
economists determine what effects will be examined in the benefits analysis, they first try to
identify all possible effects. Based on early discussions with ecologists during planning and
early in the problem formulation stage, economists begin identifying potential economic benefits
by thinking about the action under study, reviewing analyses of similar actions, and working
with the ecological assessment team and their preliminary conceptual models to understand what
ecological changes are expected.

Economists might identify various types of benefits stemming from changes to ecological
resources. The economic benefit endpoints are generally viewed as services or uses provided by
ecological resources. The types of benefit endpoints include direct market uses, direct non-
market uses, indirect non-market uses, and non-use values. Chapter 5 describes this
categorization of economic benefit endpoints and provides example services and uses that might
be considered.  This categorization of potential economic benefit endpoints reflects how directly
each service or use is experienced by an individual and the extent to which an individual can be
restricted from enjoying the service or use. Characterizing the economic benefit endpoints in
this way helps economists identify appropriate valuation techniques for each endpoint.

One method of identifying economic benefit endpoints is to develop a table that links likely
ecological changes to impacts on human uses and values (e.g., see  U.S. EPA, 1995; King, 1997,
and the U.S. Army Corps of Engineers (USAGE) approach described in Cole et al, 1996). For
example, groundwater discharges contribute to the flow or stock of water in wetlands, streams,
rivers, and lakes.  As a result, a policy that changes the quality or quantity of groundwater might
affect the services provided or supported by these surface water resources, such as drinking
water supply and recreational boating, fishing, and hunting. The economist looking at changes
to groundwater thus might list increased availability of drinking water, increased opportunities
for river recreation, or improved quality of recreational fishing as potential economic benefit
endpoints.

Exhibit 6 provides a simple illustration of how such an approach might be used to develop a
preliminary list of economic benefit endpoints.  Some of the potential  economic effects listed in
                                                                                  Page 16

-------
Exhibit 6 are not very specific and may need to be refined before the economic value of the
effect
 can be estimated, but this listing provides a starting point for economists to work with ecologists
in identifying the economic benefit endpoints that are linked to the policy or action. As
discussed in the next subsection (2.4.3), the Framework presented here recommends using the
conceptual model developed for the ecological risk assessment to identify appropriate economic
endpoints and to facilitate coordination between ecologists and economists.
                                        Exhibit 6
       Hypothetical List Linking Ecological Changes to Potential Economic Effects
   Ecological Change

   Reduced turbidity of water body
Economic Effects

Increased commercial and recreational fish harvests

Reduced water treatment costs

Improved aesthetic quality of the water
   Increased wetland acreage
Reduced costs of storm damage

Improved recovery after storm-induced combined sewer
overflows

Reduced water treatment costs

Increased commercial and recreational fishery and shellfish
harvests
2.4.3  Identifying and Defining Linkages

With the preliminary work described above, the ecologists and economists can now work
together to extend the conceptual model developed by the ecologists to include corresponding
economic benefit endpoints that might be affected. The thoroughness of the economic benefit
analysis depends on identifying and defining as many of the linkages between changes to
ecological resource(s) and changes to the economic benefit endpoints as possible. Identifying
and defining these linkages begins with a qualitative understanding of the relationships and
interactions that occur within the natural system. As noted earlier, the ecological risk assessment
team can help the economist understand these relationships by communicating with the
economist during the development of the conceptual model. The conceptual model should
clearly identify the direct and indirect effects of an action and form the basis for  explaining the
ecological cascade of effects to the economic analysts.
                                                                                   Page 17

-------
The first attempt to link economic benefit
endpoints to ecological endpoints is likely to
result in four types of findings: (1) good
matches between some ecological changes and
some economic benefit endpoints; (2) a series
of ecological changes that the economists had
not considered; (3) a series of potential
economic valuation endpoints for which there
are no clear connections to the ecological
changes represented in the conceptual model;
and (4)  a series of endpoints whose economic
benefits are ambiguous or unmeasurable.
Economists can then consider the additional
ecological changes represented in the
conceptual diagram and identify appropriate
economic benefit endpoints to reflect those
changes. Ecologists can consider whether
they have overlooked any effects suggested by
the economic endpoints and whether some of
the ecological endpoints could be redefined to
provide a more clear connection to the
remaining economic endpoints.
  Example of How this Step Might Work

It might be reasonable for economists to list
recreational and commercial fishing as a
potential economic benefit endpoint for any
change in water quality.  To define linkages
between ecological and economic endpoints,
economists work with ecologists to determine
if a proposed change in water quality will
actually have any impact on fish populations.
Once a link is identified, the nature of the
relationship needs to be defined. For
example, ecologists and economists might
discuss which fish species are most sensitive
to the change (e.g., game fish such as trout), a
threshold for effects, and the relationship of
the magnitude of the change to likely
population size.
 Importance of "Obscure" Ecological Changes

The process of linking economic benefit endpoints
to ecological endpoints can be challenging.
Economic valuation expresses benefits in terms of
human values. Improvements considered
important by ecologists (e.g., increased
biodiversity of a macroinvertebrate stream
community, see Exhibit 5) might not necessarily
be appreciated by the public.  Therefore, it can be
helpful to describe the cause-and-effect
relationship between seemingly unimportant
ecological changes and changes with obvious
implications for humans.  For example, an
increase in fishing opportunities can result from
increased fish populations that occur because the
macroinvertebrate community is healthier.
Indirectly, then, the change in the
macroinvertebrate community is valued by the
increase in fishing opportunities.
     The ecologists and economists continue
     to work together to refine the match
     between ecological and economic
     endpoints. When a new connection (or
     linkage) is identified, the economic
     valuation endpoint is added to the
     expanded conceptual model along with a
     diagrammatic explanation of the
     connection to one or more of the
     ecological changes represented in the
     ecologists' conceptual model. At this
     point in problem formulation, the goal of
     collaboration is to be all inclusive and to
     extend the conceptual diagram to include
     as many linkages between ecological
     changes and economic benefit endpoints
     as is reasonable. It is an iterative
     process, as the dotted lines looping from
     the joint conceptual diagram back into
     the individual disciplines in Exhibit 4
     indicate.

     The expanded conceptual model
     produced through this collaborative
                                                                                 Page 18

-------
process should identify the economic benefit endpoints that are likely to be affected and the
pathways by which these effects are realized. Exhibit 7 provides an example of how the
conceptual model presented in Exhibit 5 might be expanded to include economic benefit
endpoints. For example, stormwater protection is added to the outcomes of improved wetland
function and structure, which in turn reduces property losses during storms.  Other economic use
endpoints are linked to several ecological effects. Exhibit 7 illustrates the linking of economic
benefit endpoints to ecological effect endpoints for a very limited set of endpoints. This
simplified example considers only a single change, reduced nitrogen loading from local septic
systems, and only some of the potential linkages between the ecological effect of reduced
eutrophication and changes experienced by some of the economic benefit endpoints. The
iterative process of refining the list of economic benefit endpoints and their links to ecological
effects endpoints continues until agreement is reached that the important elements of the problem
are represented.

                                        Exhibit 7
                 Expanding a Conceptual Model to Include Linkages to
                          Specific Economic Benefit Endpoints
                                  Improved Local Septic Systems
                                              I
                                    Reduced Nutrient Loading
                               Reduced Eutrophication in Local Waters
                     Improved Aquatic
                         Habitat
                 Increased Macroinvertebrate
                        Abundance
                   Improved Wetland Function
                         and Structure
                            1
                         Increased
                       Fish/Shellfish
                        Populations
               Improved Storm
                  Protection
                Improved Water
                  Filtration
                            Increased
                          Migratory Bird
                          Visitation Rate
        Increased
        Shore Bird
        Population
                Improved Water
                   Quality
                Increased
               Recreational
          Fish/Shellfish Landings
Improved Bird
  Watching
Opportunities
Reduced
Property
 Losses
Improved Recreational
Swimming and Boating
    Opportunities
                                                                                      Page 19

-------
The economists and ecologists also should consider whether there are any feedback loops
between ecological and economic endpoints. For example, if improved water quality results in
increased fish populations and increased recreational fishing, the potential effects of overfishing
on the same fish populations should be considered.

For each economic benefit endpoint, economists and ecologists must define the linkages and
relationships between the ecological changes and the economic endpoints in sufficient detail to
move forward with prioritization of the endpoints and development of the analysis plans. In
defining the linkages, the economist must gather sufficient information from the ecological risk
assessment team to be able to estimate the potential magnitude of the change to each economic
endpoint and to determine what techniques might be appropriate for estimating the monetary
value of the change.

2.5    PROBLEM FORMULATION - PRIORITIZING ENDPOINTS AND SELECTING
       VALUATION TECHNIQUES

Time and resource constraints generally require that the ecological and economic benefit
analyses focus on fully explaining and quantifying changes to only a limited number of
endpoints.  This section discusses where coordination between ecologists and  economists is
needed to prioritize ecological and economic endpoints for analysis.

2.5.1  Prioritization  Criteria

From the ecologist's perspective, EPA has defined several criteria that can help identify the most
important and useful endpoints for an ecological risk or benefit assessment (U.S. EPA, 1998):

•      Ecological relevance of an endpoint (e.g., importance to maintaining ecosystem structure
       or function);

       Susceptibility of the endpoint to the proposed actions.  Susceptibility depends on the
       sensitivity  of the endpoint to the action (e.g., plants are particularly sensitive to
       herbicides) and on the likelihood of exposure (e.g., is there a pathway by which the stress
       can reach the organisms?); and

•      Relevance  to the management goals established during the planning phase.

EPA's (1998) Guidelines for Ecological Risk Assessment discuss these criteria, and examples are
provided in Chapter 4 of this document.  Sometimes, the endpoints that best fit the ecological
selection criteria may not be those best suited for economic valuation. The  ecologists might
include endpoints that the economists do not plan to address (e.g., which ecosystem process
offers the highest signal-to-noise ratio for purposes of monitoring change after an environmental
decision is implemented).

The prioritization of benefit endpoints for the economic benefit analysis requires consideration
of several factors:
                                                                                Page 20

-------
•      Type of information required by decision-makers;

•      Expected magnitude of the change in the economic value of one benefit endpoint relative
       to other endpoints;

       Anticipated uncertainty associated with the predicted change and value of the change for
       the benefit endpoint relative to other endpoints;

•      Variation in the change to each benefit endpoint under alternative policy scenarios; and

•      Analytical feasibility considerations.

Economists generally want to  estimate the dollar value of those changes that represent the
greatest economic benefits. However, economists must also consider whether there are likely to
be significant differences in the change to the benefit endpoint under alternative policy options
and whether stakeholders or decision-makers will need information on the benefit endpoint even
if the magnitude of the economic value of the change is relatively small (U.S. EPA, 2000a). If
the purpose of conducting the  benefit analysis is to choose between alternative policy options,
the ecological changes that experience the greatest variation in economic value across policy
options might be the most important to address in detail in the economic assessment of benefits.
Similarly, there may be particular benefit endpoints that are of interest to stakeholders or
decision-makers that are given priority for detailed consideration in the economic assessment of
benefits.

The potential economic value  of the change to each economic endpoint will depend on the
magnitude of the ecological change or changes linked to that economic endpoint.  The ecological
risk assessment team can help economists determine which benefit endpoints are likely to
experience the largest or most wide-spread changes or vary most significantly across policy
options. In some cases, an ecological change that is relatively small in magnitude may provide
large economic benefits.  By working with the ecologists to develop the expanded conceptual
model and to prioritize endpoints, the economists can be sure that those ecological changes are
included in the conceptual model.  Similarly, ecologists can ensure that economists do not
overlook ecological changes that might appear to be relatively minor but in fact have widespread
or long-term consequences. Thus, by working together, the ecologists and economists can make
sure that the "joint" conceptual model encompasses a comprehensive suite of economic benefit
endpoints.

What can be measured in the ecological assessment will dictate, in part, what ecological changes
and economic effects are captured by the economic benefit analysis.  Economists need to
understand the data traditionally collected and developed by an ecological assessment and
determine how well these data address the data needs of the economic analysis. Ecologists also
need to better understand the data needs of the economic benefit analysis.  Better communication
between the  disciplines during problem formulation allows both the economists and the
ecologists to identify opportunities to slightly expand  the scope of the conceptual model,
possibly adding additional ecological endpoints or altering slightly the types of information
developed to provide for significant improvements in the economic benefit analysis.
                                                                                  Page 21

-------
Changes to endpoints that are better understood and more certain are given higher ranking than
changes to endpoints that are less well understood or more variable.  Economists want to provide
a more certain estimate of the benefits of an action to better support policy decisions. However,
where changes are potentially very large, they need to be considered even though they might be
highly variable or not well understood.

The number of benefit endpoints that can be evaluated in detail in the economic benefits analysis
depends on the type of assessment conducted for those endpoints as well as the time and
resources available for the economic assessment.  Toward the end of this prioritization process,
the ecological and economic benefit endpoints have been roughly ranked according to ecological
and economic importance.  The ecologists and economists will  need to confer and compare their
rankings of linked endpoints. Where the rankings agree (e.g., an ecological endpoint ranked as
high priority has an explicit linkage to an economic  endpoint that also is ranked as high priority),
the discussions will be short. Where the rankings disagree (e.g., an ecological endpoint is listed
as high priority, but the linked economic benefit endpoint is listed as low priority), further
discussion might help one or the other group change their ranking. Or, the ecologists might
decide to evaluate a high priority endpoint even though the economists will devote little attention
to it. Any high priority economic endpoints will need the supporting ecological analyses to  be
conducted. At the end of this step, both groups have identified  those endpoints on which they
will focus their efforts.

The next section discusses the decision criteria used to determine if a monetary, quantitative, or
qualitative economic benefit assessment is appropriate and how communication with the
ecological assessment team supports that decision.

2.5.2  Monetized, Quantitative, and Qualitative Assessments

The following issues are considered in determining whether a monetized, quantitative or
qualitative assessment of the economic benefits associated with each endpoint is appropriate:

       Need for a dollar value estimate  of the ecological benefits associated with the action;

•      Availability of appropriate economic assessment techniques (e.g., techniques for non-use
       values currently not available);

•      Compatibility of available benefit assessment techniques with the data and outputs of the
       ecological assessment; and

       Availability of relevant ecological and economic data.

The appropriate type of assessment of the economic value of ecological changes is often
determined by answering the questions posed during the planning process:  "Why is the analysis
being conducted?" "What are the questions the analysis will address?" and "What are the
decisions that these analyses will inform?"  In some cases, a qualitative or quantitative
assessment of the economic value of ecological  benefits, rather than a monetized assessment,
may be all that is necessary to support the decisionmaking process.
                                                                                  Page 22

-------
If a monetary estimate of economic benefits is needed, economists must determine if they can
provide a monetized measure of value of the change for each economic endpoint within the time
and resource constraints of the overall analysis. The ability of economists to provide a
monetized measure of benefits associated with any particular endpoint depends on the
applicability of economic valuation techniques to the situation and the availability of the data
necessary to support the analysis.  Most often, the ability of EPA to provide a monetized
measure of benefits will depend on the applicability of existing value estimates in the literature
for use in a benefits transfer analysis (see Section 6.3.9 on Benefits Transfer).  Once economists
identify the  economic benefit endpoints for which appropriate economic data and techniques are
available, they can work with ecologists to determine if the ecological assessment can provide
the information needed on the ecological changes.  For example, to apply a value from a
previous economic study to the current economic benefit assessment (i.e., to use  benefits
transfer) the economist will need a comparable measure of the ecological change as used in the
original valuation study.

A thorough  economic benefit assessment focuses not just on the effects that can be monetized,
but on the full scope of effects. Many ecological services are not provided through markets or
are not readily associated with market transactions.  As a result, it may be more difficult or
impossible to provide a dependable monetized measure of the benefits associated with many
ecological changes. For those benefits that are not monetized, a qualitative, and when possible
quantitative, assessment of the economic value of the changes provides a measure of a service's
importance and the degree of change, even when a dollar value cannot be assigned to that
change.  For those benefits that are monetized, including a thorough qualitative and quantitative
discussion of the changes that are valued supports the dollar valued generated by the analysis.
Again, the ecological assessment team can help economists  determine if some type of
quantitative assessment of the change is possible, or if a qualitative assessment must suffice.

It might not be possible for the ecological  assessment or economic analysis to assess the change
to some of the ecological endpoints considered key by the ecologists' selection criteria. For
example, certain ecological services are too  complex and too poorly understood to quantify or
monetize potential changes (e.g., carbon cycle, nitrogen cycle). Other ecological benefits are
difficult to characterize and quantify (e.g., species habitat, pollination, microclimate control).
Principe (1995) termed these "neglected" benefits because they are seldom included in benefit
assessments. EPA's resource book on Assessing the Neglected Benefits of Watershed
Management Practices (U.S. EPA, 2000b), provides further examples of ecological benefits that,
although important ecologically and economically, are rarely included in benefit assessments
because they are hard to characterize and quantify. Nonetheless, these services are extremely
important to our economic and human welfare (Dailey etaL, 1997; Dailey, 1997).

Even though the ecological assessment and economic analysis are not able to estimate a specific
change, the  economic benefit assessment should recognize that the potential impact or
improvement to the ecological service might have great value to society.  In these situations, the
economic benefit analysis  should include a detailed qualitative discussion  on the effect of the
policy or action on the ecological and economic endpoints and, if possible, describe the potential
economic significance of these changes to society.
                                                                                  Page 23

-------
2.6    PROBLEM FORMULATION - ENSURING ANALYTICAL AND DATA
       COMPATIBILITY IN THE ANALYSIS PLANS

Problem formulation for both the ecologists and the economists culminates in the development
of the analysis plan for the assessment.  Since the ecological assessment is often the main source
of information for the economist regarding how a specific action or change has affected or is
likely to affect an ecological resource, it is imperative that the analysis plans are compatible.
Having compatible analysis plans means having a common understanding of the baseline from
which effects are measured and the scenarios or policy options to examine, ensuring that the
outputs of the ecological assessment meet the needs of the economic analysis, defining
consistent spatial and temporal scales for the analyses, and determining how uncertainty will be
treated by the analyses.

Having compatible analysis plans ensures that:

•      Outputs from the ecological assessment are compatible with the needs of the economic
       benefit analysis;

•      Findings of the ecological assessment and economic benefit analysis are analytically
       consistent; and

•      Conclusions of the ecological assessment and economic benefit analysis meet the needs
       of the decisionmakers as defined during the planning stage.

During the prioritization of ecological and economic endpoints, ecologists and economists will
have discussed what information is required by the economist and if that information can be
derived from or developed during the ecological assessment.  During the analysis design phase,
ecologists and economists formalize what information is needed by economists and determine
how and when that information will be provided. They must also agree on how changes will be
described or measured (e.g., from what baseline, under what scenarios, at what level of spatial or
temporal  detail) and how any limitations or uncertainties will be represented. The following
subsections address each of the issues that must be  discussed when designing the analysis plan to
ensure compatibility between the ecological assessment and the economic analysis.

2.6.1  Establishing the Baseline and Alternative Scenarios

The baseline from which effects are measured and the specific scenarios or policy options to
consider must be consistent between the ecological assessment and the economic benefit
analysis.  EPA's (2000) Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses provides detailed guidance
on specifying the baseline for economic analyses.  According to those guidelines, the baseline
must be appropriate for the question or policy option addressed, identify a particular point in
time from which point forward the effects of the policy or action are to be assessed, and define
assumptions about underlying conditions or factors that are unknown or uncertain but will affect
the conclusions of the assessment (e.g., number of alternative fishing opportunities available).
Baseline  specification might also include determining what alternative assumptions might be
examined as part of a sensitivity analysis.  Because the baseline must be consistent with any

                                                                                Page 24

-------
other analyses conducted as part of the overall study, the parameters for defining a baseline for
the ecological assessment and economic benefit analysis may be determined during the planning
stage for the overall study. However, issues relating to baseline specification specifically related
to assessing changes to ecological resources may arise and must be resolved when developing
the analysis plan.

Defining the scenarios to examine includes defining the action or change to be evaluated, the
area(s) expected to be affected, the time period over which effects will be evaluated, and
identifying any  additional factors or actions (e.g., other regulations) that might affect the
outcome and determining how they will be accounted for in the ecological assessment and
economic benefit analysis. Many of these questions will have been addressed during the
planning stage.  However, it may be necessary to reexamine the decisions made  during the
planning stage in light of the joint conceptual  model.

2.6.2  Measuring and Modeling Linkages

The analysis plans put in writing the assessment design, the analyses that will be conducted, data
needs, measures, models to be applied, and statistical techniques to use. Both the ecological and
economic analysis plans should specify what will be measured and how changes in endpoints
will be expressed. In developing an analysis plan for the economic benefit assessment,
economists must determine how they will represent the ecological changes in the economic
analysis. Most  economic valuation approaches will require some measure of the ecological
change associated with the economic endpoint assessed (e.g., an assessment of the value of
improved swimming opportunities requires a measure of the change in water quality, an
assessment of improved wildlife viewing opportunities requires information on the estimated
change in the wildlife population). During the analysis design phase, economists must determine
if the information required by the economic analysis is specified in the ecological analysis plan.
If not, the ecologists and economists must confer until  agreement is reached on the how
ecological changes will be characterized at the end of the ecological risk/benefit assessment.
At this point,  an initial screening-level assessment might be planned to (a) assess the likelihood
of certain linkages between ecological and economic endpoints and (b) determine the sensitivity
of those relationships. If any of the results are unexpected, the endpoints for assessment might
be reprioritized.

To the extent that the conceptual model identified feedback loops between the economic and
ecological endpoints, the analysis plans must specify how those interactions will be modeled.
Such interactive models will require more  extensive coordination and cooperation  between the
ecologists and economists than models without feedback loops. For example, in assessing the
economic benefits associated with an increase in fish populations resulting from improved water
quality, economists may want to account for market adjustments in response to the increased
supply offish, namely lower commercial prices and increased consumption. The long-term net
effect of these reactions may be a slightly smaller increase in fish populations than estimated
without accounting for this market adjustment. The change in the estimated increase in the fish
population may have an impact on other ecological resources, such as piscivorus birds, that rely
on the fish population as their food source. Thus, by accounting for the economic  market
response associated with the commercial fishery, the ecological assessment may provide a better
                                                                                 Page 25

-------
estimate of the benefits to the bird populations (which also may be associated with a separate
economic benefit endpoint - bird watching).

Until recently, most economic valuation models focused on only a single change, ignoring
interactions inherent to the natural system and failing to account for interactions between
multiple economic and ecological  endpoints simultaneously. However, with advances in
ecological and economic models there will be greater opportunities for using models that capture
the interactions and feedback loops both within the ecological system and between ecological
and economic endpoints (e.g., incorporate role of human action in ecological model and reflect
effect of economic changes on human actions).

In the coordination between the ecological and economic analysis plans, there are two areas that
require substantial attention: the spatial  and temporal scales of the assessments.  These must be
matched, and issues associated with each are described in the next two subsections.

2.6.3  Matching Spatial Scales

The benefits of many ecological processes and services "play out" at a much larger spatial scale
than specific projects under consideration (Limburg, 1999).  The proposed actions and
alternatives often can be delineated geographically and often are limited to small portions of
watersheds or landscapes.  Ecosystems,  on the other hand, can  be difficult to delineate
geographically, and the spatial scale of the change in ecological benefits often is much larger
than the spatial scale of an implemented management practice.  Also, because the benefits play
out at a larger spatial scale, those services are impacted by other projects, land uses, etc., in ways
that will affect the outcome. All ecosystems lose, gain, or exchange some types of materials and
energy with neighboring ecosystems through one or more processes.

The spatial area over which ecological benefits might occur is generally larger or different from
the spatial area over which the proposed action/alternatives can be delineated because of the
cascading nature of the ecological effects.  One way to overcome this analytic difficulty and to
ensure a good match between elements of the analyses spatially is to view the natural systems as
being organized in hierarchies (O'Neill  et al, 1986). In this view, the coarser-scale entities (i.e.,
aggregates of finer-scale entities) can be separated into manageable sets of relatively
homogeneous subgroups (Costanza etal.,  1995; Vatn et al.,  1999). Watersheds or catchments
often are the largest unit of analysis for  many assessments, with finer scale units being
comprised of areas with similar slope, soils, vegetation, and microclimate.  Once units of
analysis have been defined in a series of hierarchies, the next analytic task is to maintain the
necessary finer-scale variations as one moves from the finer- to the more coarse-scale
entities/aggregations (Vatn etal., 1999). For a discussion of conducting analyses using
hierarchies based on different spatial scales, see Costanza etal. (1995), Vatn etal. (1999).

An advantage of developing the conceptual model that describes both the direct and indirect
ecological effects of an action is that each node in the model (i.e., the endpoint described in a
box with arrows entering and leaving the box) is likely to be associated with a change in the
spatial scale of ecological effects.  Thus, the ecologists can examine each node and estimate
whether the spatial scale of effects at that node is likely to be larger than the spatial scale for
                                                                                  Page 26

-------
analysis of the preceding node. To increase the utility of the conceptual model, it is helpful to
provide a description of the geographic scale and location associated with each node in the
model.

Defining the spatial area of consideration for the economic analysis is an important step that can
have significant impacts on the conclusions of the analysis.  The spatial area of consideration
defined by the ecological risk assessment serves as the starting point for defining the spatial
limits of the economic analysis. Because the economic analysis focuses on human uses
associated with ecological resources and humans are more mobile than plant and animals, the
economic analysis might consider a broader spatial area than that defined by the ecological
assessment.  The economic analysis must define an appropriate spatial area from which humans
may still make use of or otherwise benefit from the services provided by the ecological resource.
If the economic analysis can monetize benefits for only a portion  of the entire area affected, the
economic assessment's qualitative discussion should address the entire area affected and
recognize that the monetary benefits estimate represent only a portion of the benefits expected
over the entire area.

2.6.4  Matching Temporal Scales

As indicated above for the spatial scale, the benefits of many ecological processes and services
"play out" over a longer time period than a specific project under consideration (Limburg, 1999).
The activities associated with a management practice might require only weeks or months to
implement, or might occur at specified points of time each year. The ecosystem responses can
require years to decades to develop and often are reflected in changes throughout the entire
annual seasonal cycle. For the purposes of assessing the economic value of the ecological
changes, effects may need to be assessed over shorter time intervals. A thorough benefits
assessment needs to consider the role of lagged or future effects and determine how best to
account for these types of effects.  This may include a better characterization of the stream of
benefits based on scientific information on changes in environmental conditions over time. It
also may include determining an appropriate discounting scheme  for comparing future effects
against current effects (see Chapter 7 for further discussion on discounting).

Again, it can be helpful to establish a hierarchy of time steps for the analysis and
compartmentalize the analysis accordingly (Vatn et al, 1999; Costanza et al, 1995).

2.6.5  Data Limitations  and Uncertainty

Evaluation of uncertainty should be a theme throughout the analysis phase that follows problem
formulation. The analysis plans should specify how uncertainty will be addressed. Several
sources of uncertainty need to be considered.  These include human error, natural variability in
parameters, data gaps, uncertainty about a parameter's true value, uncertainty introduced by
models that attempt to predict real-world processes, and other  sources. An  important distinction
to maintain throughout the analysis is the difference between natural variability, which can be
quantified using various statistics, and uncertainties due to lack of information.
                                                                                  Page 27

-------
The economic benefits analysis should recognize the uncertainties in the ecological assessment
process as well as the uncertainties inherent in economic analysis.  The level of uncertainty in
the ecological assessment process as well as the economic valuation process is often substantial.

As discussed in detail in EPA's (2000) Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses., the issue is
not to avoid uncertainty but to recognize and account for uncertainty and provide information
that is useful to decision makers.  As noted in the Guidelines, to adequately address uncertainty,
the analysis should: use the expected or most plausible outcomes; discuss all key assumptions,
biases and omissions; include sensitivity analyses for key assumptions; and justify the inputs and
assumptions used based on the results of the sensitivity analyses.  (See Chapter 7 for further
discussion on accounting for variability and uncertainty.)

2.7    CONDUCTING THE ASSESSMENTS

Once the analysis plans are complete, the actual analyses can begin.  In general, the ecological
assessment must be conducted first to provide the inputs on predicted changes in ecological
endpoints for the economic assessment. The ecological exposure and response assessments are
conducted by the ecological risk assessment team independent of the economists. In other
words, if problem formulation and planning for the analyses are carefully conducted, there
should be little need for communication between the economists and the ecologists during the
ecological analyses. Often, however,  unexpected data gaps or unexpected interim modeling
results might require discussions between the ecologists and economists to resolve such issues.

2.7.1  Ecological Risk/Benefit Assessment

During the analysis phase, the ecological risk/benefit assessment team collects the data specified
in the ecological analysis plan.  The team then conducts both an exposure assessment and an
ecological response assessment. The exposure assessment evaluates the potential sources of
stress or change, their distribution in the environment,  and their overlap with ecological
receptors. The response analysis attempts to quantify exposure-response relationships and the
relationship between measures of response and the ecological assessment endpoints. For
economic assessments of ecological benefits, it is insufficient to identify thresholds for effects,
as sometimes is done in ecological risk assessments to identify environmental levels of concern
or cleanup goals for contaminated waste sites.  The ecological risk assessment conducted for an
economic benefits assessment must estimate the type and magnitude of ecological changes to
allow the economists to predict the economic benefits (i.e., positive economic changes) from an
environmental decision.

Because the ecological endpoints can  include both direct and indirect effects, the exposure and
response analyses generally will include two types of assessments. The first is an analysis of the
relationship between the magnitude and extent of the initial action/stressor and the magnitude
and extent of direct ecological effects of that stressor.  The second is an analysis of the
relationship between the magnitude and extent of changes in those initial ecological endpoints to
the magnitude and extent of responses in the endpoints down the cascade of effects depicted in
the conceptual model.  The analysis phase concludes with descriptions of the findings from the
                                                                                  Page 28

-------
exposure and response assessments.  Additional discussion of this phase of the ecological risk
assessment is provided in Chapter 4.

The final phase of an ecological risk assessment is risk characterization (see Exhibit 2). This
phase integrates the findings from the exposure and response assessments to characterize the
predicted changes in ecological endpoints. For ecological risk assessments for contaminated
sites, risk characterization often consists of a simple question. Does the exposure level exceed a
threshold for effects? For ecological risk assessments conducted to support economic benefit
analyses, the emphasis of risk characterization needs to be predicting the magnitude and extent
(both spatial and temporal) of changes in the ecological assessment endpoints.

Ecological risk assessment conducted to support economic benefit assessments also differ from
ecological risk assessments for contaminated sites in how uncertainty in the assessment is
handled.  For risk assessments for contaminated sites, data gaps are generally addressed using
conservative assumptions. Moreover, exposure assessments generally focus on possible high-
end exposures (e.g., upper 90th percentile). That is because the risk management goal at
hazardous waste sites often is to be reasonably sure that a site is "clean" (i.e., unlikely to  cause
adverse effects to the assessment  endpoints) after site remediation is complete. In other words,
the assessment is designed to ensure a "reasonable margin of safety". For an economic benefit
analysis, on the other hand, uncertainty might be handled in other ways.

For economic benefit assessments that address large areas (e.g., national, regional, or state
assessments), best estimates, instead of high-end estimates, often are the most useful for
characterizing ecological risks. Estimated mean values for the change in an ecological endpoint,
with some type of confidence interval on those estimates, provides the economists with numbers
that can be added or multiplied in the economic assessment without compounding conservative
biases. Lower and upper percentile estimates of the degree of change in an ecological  endpoint
also are useful to the economists.  Plausible worst or best case scenarios are generally only
useful as bounding exercises for the assessment.

2.7.2  Qualitative and Quantitative Economic Assessment

Following the effect-by-effect approach to benefit analysis discussed above, economists proceed
with the qualitative, quantitative,  or monetized assessment of changes for each endpoint.
Economists begin by gathering economic data and developing their models, as called for by their
analysis plan, in anticipation of the final input from the ecological risk assessment. At this  point,
economists also collect any additional information and data required for their qualitative  and
quantitative assessments. Once the monetized benefits associated with the various economic
endpoints are estimated,  the dollar values are summed together. It is important, however, that
economists emphasize that the monetized benefits estimate reflects only a portion of the total
economic benefits expected to accrue from the action. This statement must be supported by
strong qualitative and quantitative assessments of other benefits not captured by the monetized
assessment.

If models or value estimates from other studies are used in the assessment, the analysis must
describe the source and provide some assessment of the confidence associated with the source.
                                                                                  Page 29

-------
For example, if multiple high-quality studies have produced a similar value estimate, the
economists can have more confidence in using this value estimate in their benefit calculation
(U.S. EPA, 2000a).

Chapter 6 discusses in detail the various economic techniques for estimating the economic value
of changes to different types of economic benefit endpoints. Economists will likely apply more
than one valuation technique in estimating the total benefits.  Care must be taken in designing
and implementing the economic analysis to avoid double counting of benefits, particularly when
applying more than one method to estimate the value of changes to related benefit endpoints.
Additionally, the economic analysis should recognize any negative consequences of the action or
policy under study that may offset some of the beneficial improvements.

2.8    CHARACTERIZING AND PRESENTING RESULTS

For many assessments, ecologists and economists will present their results separately, usually
with the results of the ecological assessment first. Because characterization of ecological
risks/benefits provides the input to the economic analysis, it is important that the presentation of
ecological changes address several factors: the types of ecological changes expected, the
magnitudes of those changes spatially, temporally, and per unit area (i.e., severity), and the
certainty associated with those estimates. The presentation of the ecological changes should
present the conceptual model and assessment endpoints, review and summarize major areas of
uncertainty and potential bias, discuss the degree of scientific consensus in key areas of
uncertainty, identify major data gaps, describe any assumptions used to bridge information gaps
(U.S. EPA, 1998), and indicate how the uncertainty in the results might be magnified through the
cascade of ecological effects considered.

In addition to the formal report of the findings for the ecological risk assessment, collaboration
between the ecological risk assessment and economics teams might help to explain the
relationships between the ecological endpoints addressed by the ecological assessment and the
economic endpoints identified in the economic benefit analysis.

The results from the economic benefit analysis will present the  prioritized list of economic
effects, discuss the criteria used to select the economic endpoints examined in detail by the
benefit analysis, and discuss how the economic value of the effects was assessed.  The monetary
benefits estimated for some  of the changes will be accompanied by the qualitative and
quantitative assessment of other benefits that were not monetized. If possible, the qualitative
assessment should discuss the potential magnitude of the economic benefits for any priority
endpoints that  are not accounted for by the quantitative and monetized assessment. The final
report should also discuss to some degree the other effects identified that were deemed less
important to the economic analysis. Finally, the results of the economic analysis must disclose
any source of error in the analysis and the potential impact of such error on the results. The
presentation of results should identify any  possibility of double-counting of benefits, any
limitations of the analysis, and any potential imprecision and uncertainty associated with the
benefit estimates.  In discussing the potential impact of any source of imprecision or
uncertainty, economists should discuss whether the analysis is likely to over- or under-estimate
the economic value of benefits.
                                                                                  Page 30

-------
The results presented also may include information and details that are needed for other
analyses. For example, an equity analysis may require information on the geographic
distribution of effects, the distribution of ecological effects and economic benefits across
different ethnic or economic classes of the human population, or the distribution of ecological
effects and economic benefits over time.

2.9    CONCLUDING REMARKS

Economists and ecologists have different views and perspectives that  are important to recognize.
Closer coordination can be encouraged by understanding how the disciplines differ and
acknowledging these differences.  In conclusion, this section identifies some areas in which
economists and scientists may find they have different approaches or interpretations.

•      Perspective. Economists approach the identification and valuation of changes to
       ecological resources differently than ecologists and other scientists. For example, human
       activities and welfare are the focus of economists while ecologists are concerned with
       complete ecological systems and the interactions between ecological components, which
       may or may not include effects on humans.

•      Terminology.  Each discipline has its own terminology, including different units of
       measure. Even common words such as "value," "benefit," and "function" have different
       meanings across disciplines.  To improve interdisciplinary coordination, care  needs to be
       taken to define and use terms consistently.

•      Scale. Part of interdisciplinary coordination is understanding how a change will be
       measured. This requires that ecologists and economists agree  on the units of
       measurement and discuss the spatial and temporal boundaries of the analysis.

•      Focus.  The ranking of endpoints will likely differ between the ecological and economic
       assessment.  Additionally, the approach for assessing changes  may differ (e.g.,
       economists may measure only the direct change,  without addressing system or feedback
       effects).  Such differences are partially a consequence of the training associated with each
       discipline but also reflect important differences in the characteristics of the systems
       studied by the respective disciplines.

•      Metrics.  Economists focus on the effect of changes to human  welfare and typically want
       to standardize effects or welfare changes into  dollars to compare effects that may be
       dissimilar.  Other metrics may be appropriate  for a qualitative  and quantitative
       description  of ecological and economic effects.
                                                                                  Page 31

-------
References and Further Reading

Ahearn, M.C. 1997. "Why Economists Should Talk to Scientists and What They Should Ask:
Discussion." Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics., July, 29(1): 113-116.

Bertollo, P. 1998. "Assessing Ecosystem Health in Governed Landscapes: A Framework for
Developing Core Indicators." Ecosystem Health 4(1): 33-51.

Bockstael, N.E., K.E. McConnell, and I.E. Strand. 1989. "Measuring the Benefits of
Improvements in Water Quality:  The Chesapeake Bay." Marine Resource Economics 6(1):
1-18.

Cole, R.A., et al. 1996. Linkages Between Environmental Outputs and Human Services, IWR
Report 96-R-4. Prepared for U.S. Army Corps of Engineers, Evaluation of Environmental
Investment Research Program.

Costanza, R (ed.). 1991. Ecological Economics: The Science of Management and
Sustainability. Columbia University Press, New York.

Costanza, R., L. Wainger, and N. Bockstael.  1995.  Integrated ecological economic systems
modeling:  theoretical issues and practical applications. In: J.W. Milon and J.F. Shogren (eds.),
Integrating Economic and Ecological Indicators. Practical Methods for Environmental Policy
Analysis.  Praeger, Westport, MA; pp. 45-66.

Daily, G. C., S. Alexander, P.R. Ehrlich, L. Goulder, J. Lubchenco, P.A. Matson, H.A. Mooney,
S. Postel, S.H. Shneider, D. Tilman, and G.M. Woodwell.  1997. Ecosystem services: benefits
supplied to human societies by natural ecosystems.  Ecological Society of America, Issues in
Ecology, Number 2, Spring 1997.

Daily, G.,  ed.  1997.  Nature's Services: Societal Dependence on Natural Ecosystems.
Washington, D.C.: Island Press.

DeBellevue, E.B., T. Maxwell, R. Costanza,  and M. Jacobsen.  1993.  "Development of a
Landscape Model for the Patuxent River Watershed." Discussion Paper #10, Maryland
International Institute for Ecological Economics, Solomons, MD.

Fitz, H.C., R.  Costanza, and E. Reyes.  1993. The Everglades Landscape Model (ELM):
Summary Report of Task 2, Model Development. Report to the South Florida Water
Management District, Everglades Research Division.

Fitz, H.C.  E.B. DeBellevue, R. Costanza, R. Boumans, T. Maxwell, L. Wainger, and F. Sklar.
1995. "Development of a General Ecosystem Model (GEM) for a Range of Scales and
Ecosystems.  Ecological Modeling (in press).
                                                                               Page 32

-------
Kaoru, Y., V. K., and J.L. Liu. 1995. "Using Random Utility Models to Estimate the
Recreational Value of Estuarine Resources." American Journal of Agricultural Economics,
February, 77: 141-151.

King, D.M.  1997.  Using Ecosystem Assessment Methods in Natural Resource Damage
Assessment, Paper #2. Prepared for U.S. Department of Commerce, NOAA, Damage
Assessment and Restoration Program.

Limburg, K.E. 1999. Estuaries, ecology, and economic decisions: an example of perceptual
barriers and challenges to understanding. Ecological Economics 30:185-188.

Milon, J.W., C. Kiker, and D. Lee.  1997. "Ecosystem Management and the Florida Everglades:
The Role of Social Scientists." Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, July, 29(1): 99-
107.

Musser, W.N. 1997.  "Why Economists Should Talk to Scientists and What They Should Ask:
Discussion." Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, July, 29(1): 109-112.

O'Neill, R.V., D.L. DeAngelis, J.B. Waide, and T.F. Allen. 1986. A Hierarchical Concept of
Ecosystems. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.

Principe, P.  1995.  "Ecological Benefits Assessment: A Policy-Oriented Alternative to Regional
Ecological Risk Assessment." Human and Ecological Risk Assessment 1(4): 423-435.

Scodari, P.  1992.  Wetland Protection Benefits. Draft Report.  Prepared for the Office of Policy,
Planning, and Evaluation, U.S. EPA. Grant No. CR-817553-01.

U.S. EPA. 1995. A Framework for Measuring the Economic Benefits ofGroundwater. Office of
Water. EPA/230/B-95/003. October.

U.S. EPA. 1997. A Conceptual Model for the Economic Valuation of Ecosystem
Damages Resulting from Ozone Exposure. Draft Report. Prepared by Science Applications
International Corporation, for the Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards, U.S. EPA.

U.S. EPA. 1997.  Guidance on Cumulative Risk Assessment. Washington, DC: Science Policy
Council.

U.S. EPA. 1998.  Guidelines for Ecological Risk Assessment. Risk Assessment Forum.
EPA/630/R-95/002F.

U.S. EPA. 2000a. Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses.  Office of the Administrator.
EPA/240/R-00/003. September.

U.S. EPA. 2000b. Assessing the Neglected Ecological Benefits of Water shed Management
Practices: A Resource Book.  Office of Water. April.
                                                                               Page 33

-------
U.S. EPA. 2001. Risk Characterization Handbook.  Memorandum from W. Michael McCabe,
Deputy Administrator, Office of the Administrator; Washington, DC: Office of the
Administrator (January 10).

Vatn, A., L. Bakken, P. Botterweg, and E. Romstad.  ECECMOD: an interdisciplinary modeling
system for analyzing nutrient and soil losses from agriculture. Ecological Economics 30:189-
205.
                                                                               Page 34

-------
3.0  IMPORTANT PRINCIPLES OF ECOLOGY AND
      ECOLOGICAL ASSESSMENT
This chapter defines some basic terms and concepts used by ecologists and explains how these
concepts can be applied in conducting an ecological assessment.  First, this chapter defines an
ecosystem and levels of ecological organization and examples of endpoints at each level (Section
3.1). Next, this chapter describes interactions that occur within ecosystems,  including the
concepts of "food chain," "food web," and "energy flow," competition, predation, and symbiosis
(Section 3.2). The chapter then examines what attributes of ecosystems and ecosystem entities
are of value both to society and to sustaining ecosystems themselves (3.3). This chapter
concludes by describing different standard approaches to ecological assessments and why EPA's
ecological risk assessment process is used in the proposed framework for the economic
assessment of ecological benefits (Section 3.4).

3.1   DEFINING ECOSYSTEM AND OTHER LEVELS OF ECOLOGICAL
      ORGANIZATION
3.1.1 Definitions

According to the Institute of
Ecosystem Studies "Ecology is the
scientific study of the processes
influencing the distribution and
abundance of organisms, the
interactions among organisms, and
the interactions between organisms
and the transformation and flux of
energy and matter."  An ecosystem
can be defined in various ways, but
one definition that is particularly
useful is "a spatially explicit unit of
the Earth that includes all of the
organisms, along with all
components of the abiotic
environment within its boundaries"
(Likens,  1992). The  concept of an
ecosystem can be applied at any
scale ranging, for example,  from a
small pond to an entire mountain
range. Because ecology is
concerned not only with organisms     ^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^
but with  energy flows and material
cycles on land, in water, and in air, ecology is often defined as the "study of the structure and
function of nature."
              Ecosystem Concepts

Ecosystems refer to a system formed by the
interaction of a group of organisms and their
environment. An ecosystem may be a pond or the
entire globe. It can be natural or artificial. All
ecosystems are composed of components, structure,
and processes (functions). Components are the
plants, animals, soil, air, and water. Structure refers
to spatial and temporal distribution of those
components. Processes are the flow of energy and
the cycling of materials and nutrients through space
and time.

Ecosystems occur in geographic arrangements.
Smaller ecosystems exist within larger ones. The
scale selected and the boundaries used to define an
ecosystem depend on the problem or question to be
addressed.

Source: Appendix A in U.S. Department of the Interior. 1994.
Ecosystem Management in the National Park Service:
                                                                             Page 35

-------
3.1.2  Levels of Biological Organization

There are five levels of biological organization that are conventionally recognized and
potentially useful in ecological risk/benefit assessments:

       Individual,
       Population,
•      Community,
•      Ecosystem, and
•      Landscape.

Ecological assessments do not address the sub-organismal levels of organization (organ systems
and cells), nor do they generally address the larger scales of organization of biomes and the
biosphere. The levels of organization listed above are not defined by the environment. Rather
they are defined by scientists to facilitate our understanding of relationships within and among
ecological systems. Thus, these levels can be described as criteria for observation and analysis
(Allen and Hoekstra,  1992).

A species is a group of individuals that are able to successfully interbreed. In a species, slight
biological variations,  both genetic and apparent, will exist among individuals. A population is a
group of organisms of the same species that live in the same place, and have the potential to
reproduce with one another during their lifetimes. A community is an organized assemblage or
association of species in a prescribed area or a specific habitat.  An ecosystem, defined above
and described in more detail below, can be viewed as a biotic (i.e., living) community
functioning within its abiotic (i.e., nonliving) environment. A landscape comprises a group of
spatially contiguous ecosystems and is usually defined in geographic terms, such as a watershed.

Ecosystems are often defined in terms of their structural and functional components. Structural
components are physical elements present in the environment. Examples include soil, nutrients,
water,  and biological  entities such as plants, animals, and microorganisms. Functional
components are processes or interactions that support the structural components, such as nutrient
cycling and energy flow.  It is the pathways of energy  flow and cycles of matter that help to
determine ecosystem  boundaries for our purposes of observation.

3.1.3  Interactions Within Ecosystems

In an ecosystem, the biological community and the abiotic elements of the environment (e.g.,
water,  soil) are bound together by action and reaction,  defined by the reciprocal effects of the
physical environment on an organism and an organism on the physical environment.
Temperature, moisture, light and other kinds of radiation, texture and chemical composition of
soil or water,  the presence or absence of gases and chemicals, gravity, pressure, and sound can
all have profound effects on organisms.  Examples of interactions between an organism and its
physical surroundings would be rising river levels forcing muskrats to abandon burrows and
move to higher ground or the use of sunlight by plants as an energy source.  Organisms
themselves can  also affect the physical environment through their activities, thereby indirectly
affecting other organisms. Examples  include beavers damming streams, which changes the
                                                                                  Page 36

-------
aquatic community, and earthworms burrowing through and aerating soil, which improves plant
growth.

In an ecosystem, interactions also occur among individuals within a population and between
individuals of different species. For example, the social behavior exhibited by different
members of a wolf pack is an example of interactions occurring between individuals within a
population. Predator-prey interactions between wolves and mice are interactions that occur
between members of different species.

To understand the influence of the various types of interactions described above on ecosystem
structure and function, it is important to view more than one level of biological organization.
Individual-level effects, such as mortality and reduced reproductive success, can have
population-level effects, such as decreasing or increasing population size and density.  On the
other hand, population-level processes can compensate for individual-level effects. For example,
in some types of species, increased adult mortality might be compensated for by increased
survivorship of younger animals to maturity.

Population Growth. Interactions among individuals within a population and harvesting of
energy and materials from food allow animals to reproduce and increase in local abundance.
Population growth rate is a function of birth rates, death rates, time to maturity, and reproductive
success.  Population growth rate also depends on the immigration of individuals from other
geographic areas into the population and the rate at which individuals emigrate in search of
better habitat.  Reproduction by some species that have just recently invaded a new geographic
area (e.g., introduced exotic or invasive species) is not hampered by predation or competition for
resources.  Such populations increase in abundance without check (i.e., exhibit density-
independent growth) for some period of time.  During that period, the species "intrinsic rate of a
natural increase" (i.e., the maximal rate at which offspring can be produced) governs the
population  growth rate.  Species that mature quickly and produce large numbers of offspring that
can survive under favorable conditions have a high intrinsic rate of natural increase. Initially,
when population density is low, population growth might follow an exponentially increasing
function. Eventually, however, resources available for growth and reproduction will become
limiting,  and birth and death rates will depend on population density. This situation is called
density dependent population regulation.  Such populations are characterized by relatively stable
population  densities (i.e., an equilibrium situation). When population growth rates are density
dependent, an increase in the rate of loss of juveniles (e.g., harvesting eggs) or adults (e.g.,
hunting) is  compensated for (within limits) by increased survival and/or reproductive rates by the
remaining population. This is the basic principle underlying management  of fisheries and game
populations.

Life History Strategies. Interactions between a species and its environment over time result in
the evolution of traits in the species that are adapted to that environment.  Some species that have
evolved in an environment that is densely populated tend to have few offspring in which they
invest heavily to improve the offspring's ability  to compete with other individuals.  Species with
this type  of life history have been called K-selected (Wilson and Bossert, 1971). Facing resource
limitations, these species have evolved to mature relatively late and attempt to reproduce
repeatedly (e.g., annual) over their lifespan. Moreover, at each reproductive effort, they produce
only a few offspring that exhibit a high survivorship.  These species also tend to be characterized

                                                                                   Page 37

-------
by longer life spans and larger body size. Whales, elephants, and seabirds are good examples of
K-selected species. At the other end of the spectrum of life history strategies are the r-selected
species (Wilson and Bossert, 1971). Such species evolve where resources for reproduction and
growth are not limiting but might exhibit a patchy distribution in the environment.  Under these
circumstances, the best strategy is simply to maximize the number of offspring produced,
investing little in each of the individual offspring. These species also tend to reproduce one time
during their life, producing large numbers of offspring that exhibit poor survivorship except
where they encounter an "empty" patch of habitat. Weeds are classic examples of r-selected
species.

Competition.  Competitive interactions are those in which two or more species tend to depress
each other's population growth rates and abundance (Gotelli, 1998). There are several different
types of interactions between species that fit this general definition. Exploitation competition
occurs when species compete with each other for the same resource (e.g., food).  For example,
domestic cattle and bison compete for food (grasses) on open range lands in several areas of the
mid-western United States.  Interference competition occurs when one species interferes with the
ability of another species to exploit a resource (Gotelli, 1998).  An example would be a plant
species that releases toxic chemicals into the soil, thereby preventing other plants from
germinating and growing in that soil.  Another example of interference competition is  introduced
(i.e., non-native) species of vines that cover other plants, thereby reducing the solar energy
available to the covered plants, stunting their growth and eventually killing them. Pre-emptive
competition occurs where species compete with each other over space (Gotelli,  1998). Examples
include competition for anchorage in the rocky intertidal zone of New England coastal areas by
barnacles and mussels.

If environmental conditions were constant over space and time, the population density of those
species best suited for those conditions would increase  at the expense of other species.
However, environmental conditions vary substantially over time and with geography (e.g.,
altitude, exposure to the sun, soil conditions, rainfall patterns).  This environmental variation
helps to maintain a number of species in competition with each other because the competitive
edge among species changes as the environmental conditions change. One species might have a
competitive advantage under some conditions, but be at a competitive disadvantage under other
conditions.

Predation. Predation is a direct interaction between two species in which an individual of one
species consumes an individual of the other species (e.g., as when a hawk captures and
consumes a rabbit).  This interaction results in removal of individuals and biomass from the prey
species' population. The relationship between predator and prey often results in oscillations in
their relative abundances. For example, when a particular prey species prospers under favorable
environmental conditions, it tends to increase in abundance. The population of predators can
respond in two ways.  In the short-term, the predator can change its behavior (i.e., a functional
response) and include more of that prey species in its diet. Over the longer-term, the predator
population abundance can increase as its death rate from starvation decreases and reproductive
success increases. This increase in predator abundance is self-limiting, however.  Increasing
predation pressure tends to reduce the prey populations, resulting in starvation, reduced
reproductive success, and a reduction in the abundance of the predator species.  This feedback
system usually results in a reasonably stable equilibrium ratio of predator to prey, although,

                                                                                  Page 38

-------
minor to moderate oscillations in that ratio can occur in response to changing environmental
conditions.

Some species of animals (e.g., mice, deer) are typically held at densities lower than their food
resource base could support because of predation. Removal of the predators in such systems
generally results in increases in the prey population until some other factor becomes limiting
(e.g., food resources). Where prey are considered pests (e.g., many insect species), removal or
loss of the predators for any reason can result in an outbreak of the pest species. Such outbreaks
often cause serious economic losses ingriculture and silviculture.

Herbivory.  Herbivores consume plant materials, usually in a way that does not kill the
individual plant. Animals that feed on grasses (e.g., bison, cattle) tend to have digestive systems
adapted for extracting nutrients from very fibrous plant materials and must consume large
quantities of food to satisfy their metabolic (i.e., caloric) needs.  Species that feed on new growth
(e.g., rabbits), with high protein and low fiber content, can survive on lower total quantities of
plant material.  A different type of herbivory is the consumption of plant seeds, which are rich in
both protein and lipids.  Many species of birds and small rodents specialize in harvesting seeds.
In general, however, seed eaters (i.e., gramnivores) generally have little impact on the abundance
of many plant species because of the prolific production of seeds by those plant species.

Herbivores generally can detoxify a wider array of chemicals than can carnivores (i.e.,
predators).  This ability results from an evolutionary arms race between plants and herbivores.
The plants cannot "escape" from an herbivore; instead, they must develop defenses that work in
situ.  Over evolutionary time, plants have developed a substantial array of defenses, including
toxic substances stored in their tissues, to discourage herbivores from eating them. The toxic
substances often cause an herbivore to be acutely ill.  Animals that recover from that experience
will avoid eating that species of plant in the future. In response, however, over evolutionary
time, herbivores have been developing metabolic pathways to detoxify the toxic chemicals found
in plants. Carnivores (at least north temperate  species), on the other hand, have not needed to
develop elaborate detoxification pathways because their prey usually cannot afford to use
chemicals in their body tissues as a defense.

Pollination. Pollination is a mutually beneficial interaction between a flowering plant and its
pollinator (e.g., bee, butterfly).  The flowering  plant offers rewards (e.g., nectar with a high sugar
content) to attract the pollinators.  The flower shape of the plant has evolved so that as the
pollinator feeds on the reward, it becomes covered in the pollen  of that plant. When the
pollinator moves on to the next individual of that plant species, the pollen can be transferred and
fertilize the eggs of that individual.  Thus, pollinators help plants reproduce sexually,
maintaining genetic variability among individuals. Many species of plants cannot self-fertilize,
and thus require their pollinators in order to reproduce at all.

Symbiosis.  Another beneficial interaction occurs in symbiotic relationships, where two
organisms in close association with each other benefit from the association.  Examples include
the relationship between corals and the algae that grow in their tissues, the relationship between
an alga and its host fungus to form a lichen (one of the few organisms that can live on bare rocks
and begin the process of soil formation), between "cleaner" shrimp and the fish that they clean,
and between acacia ants and the acacia trees they protect in return for nectar and shelter.  In

                                                                                   Page 39

-------
many symbiotic relationships, death of one member of the pair sooner or later results in illness or
death of the other. For example, death of the algae living in the tissues of corals, which can be
recognized by the "bleached" appearance of the coral, often is followed by death of the coral
organisms themselves.

In summary, there are many types of interactions within and among species that occur in all
ecosystems.  For this reason, direct impacts (or benefits) of an activity on one species tend to
produce a cascade of effects through an ecosystem because of the interactions among species in
the ecosystem.

3.2    UNDERSTANDING ECOSYSTEM STRUCTURE AND FUNCTION

Ecosystems may be as large as unbroken tracts of forest and grassland or smaller than a pond.
The ecosystem is an energy-and-material-processing system, receiving abiotic and biotic inputs.
The driving force is the energy of the sun.  Abiotic inputs include oxygen, carbon dioxide, and
nutrients. Nutrients become available via weathering of the Earth's crust and precipitation.
Biotic inputs include organic materials, such as living organisms and detritus matter (i.e., dead
and/or decaying organisms).

The ecosystem itself consists of three components:

       Producers that derive their energy from the sun (i.e., photosynthetic plants);

       Consumers and decomposers that use the energy fixed by the producers and eventually
       return nutrients to the ecosystem; and

•      Dead organic material and inorganic substrates that act as short-term nutrient pools and
       support the cycling of nutrients within the ecosystem.

The most basic functions of the ecosystem are photosynthesis and decomposition.
Photosynthesis is the process by which green plants utilize the energy of the sun to convert
carbon dioxide and water into carbohydrates.  Through photosynthesis, plants are able to capture
the sun's energy  and drive the majority of metabolic activities in the living world. Decomposers
are responsible for the return of nutrients to the ecosystem and a final dissipation of energy to the
environment.
                                                                                 Page 40

-------
                                      Exhibit 8
                           Trophic Level Organization
              o>
              .o
              §
                                            Quaternary consumers
                                                  (carnivores)
Tertiary consumers
   (carnivores)
                                  Secondary consumers
                                       (carnivores)
                                   Primary consumers
                                       (herbivores)
                                      Producers
The "food chain" is a concept that describes the movement of energy and nutrients from one
feeding group of organisms to another in a series that begins with producers and ends with
consumers. The food chain concept specifies a sequence of organisms, each of which feeds on
the preceding group. The trophic structure ("trophic" means "feeding") of a community is based
on the food chains in the community (see Exhibit 8).  A simple food chain might be: oak leaf ^
caterpillar O small bird O hawk. One useful approach in defining relationships among
organisms is to group organisms based on their trophic levels (i.e., their position in the food
chain).

The major categories for trophic organization are producers, primary consumers, and secondary
consumers. However, ecosystems are too complex to be characterized by a  single, unbranched
food chain. Instead, the transfer of materials and energy from one type of organism to another is
better described as a food web (see Exhibit 9).

The food web for most communities is very complex, including many species and trophic
groups. Several primary consumers may feed on the same plant species. For example, several
insect species might feed on one tree. On the other hand, one species may feed on several
different plants. Also, some species may feed at more than one trophic level. For instance, owls
may  eat primary consumers, such as field mice, and also prey on higher level organisms like
snakes. It is more correct, then, to draw relationships between these trophic levels, not as a
simple chain, but as a more elaborate interwoven food web. Complexity of the food creates
                                                                                Page 41

-------
                                  Foocft^WHfc&els
                                Terrestrial Food Web
 Food webs can be described from various points of view.  A sink web is a conceptual model
of a food web that is constructed by tracing trophic links downwards from a single species,
usually a top predator, to the primary producers (Hall and Raffaelli, 1993). This conceptual
model is useful when assessing the poten^g^for a bioaccumulative contaminant in the
                                                 such as bald eagles and wolves. A
                                                   links upward from a species, using
                                                 ;s)l£hairthose species that feed on it
                                                  odel carrots useful when tracing the
                                                                   ?& is constructed
                                                        components"
                                                       Exhibit 9 is
Environment to cause adverse effects in
 'ource web is a food web constructed by
 basal resource (e.J|fca plantjfeecies, an in^eWcslpect
 irectly or indirectly^^p;^^Raffaelli, 1/993).
 otential effects of pesSBBp ap^pl^ed to rfne type
 y delineating the bo$pdjftFi<§p^f a co^nimunity, identQ
 ommunity, and de^rmining theXeedi/gtisks arm
 xample of a community web. Cor
 nvironmental n/edia result in colfe^n^tiea^: man>
 eb.
                                                                       the — •
                             Mouse^
                                                                                food
                        Grasses and seeds
                                                               Bushes with fruit
                                                                                 C83006-2
opportunities for amelioration of impacts on a particular food chain, but also makes it possible
for there to be indirect effects that are larger than the direct effects.

Two processes occur in an ecosystem through the food web: energy transfer and nutrient cycling.
Both energy and nutrients are transferred from plants (producers) to herbivores to carnivores
(primary and secondary consumers) and from all preceding levels to the decomposers through
the food web. By tracing the energy transfers and nutrient cycles, the ecologist is able to analyze
the changes in an entire ecosystem.
Terrestrial and aquatic ecosystems tend to have somewhat different patterns of energy flow and
nutrient cycling. In terrestrial systems, the major energy input is from the sun, while in some
aquatic systems, for example small streams within forests, additional energy inputs come from
the terrestrial environment from plants, insects, and other animals.  In forest ecosystems, a
substantial proportion of the organic matter in the system can be in the form of dead and
decomposing organic matter, the leaf litter.  Hairston and Hairston  (1993) estimate that 95
percent of the net primary production (NPP) by plants in temperate forests reaches the forest
floor, while only about 15 percent of the NPP in a lake reaches the  lake bottom.  Once on the
bottom,  only a fraction of the detritus in a lake is consumed; the rest accumulates annually in the
sediments where it might be permanently "lost."  In terrestrial ecosystems, detritivore-based food
webs tend to be at least as important as herbivore-based food webs, whereas herbivore-based
food webs tend to predominate in aquatic ecosystems (Hairston and Hairston,  1993).
The length of food chains in terrestrial ecosystems tends to be shorter than the length of food
chains in aquatic ecosystems (Hairston and Hairston, 1993; Oksanen, 1991).  Some ecologists
have even proposed that the length of food chains in terrestrial ecosystems typically is two steps,
                                                                                 Page 42

-------
while in large open water systems (e.g., large lakes), the food chain length typically is three steps
(Briand and Cohen, 1987; Pimm, 1980, 1982). As the difference in food chain length would
suggest, bioaccumulation of contaminants in terrestrial ecosystems is less prevalent than
bioaccumulation of contaminants in aquatic ecosystems.
                Example of Translation and Magnification of the Effects
                     of Pollutant Discharges Through the Food Web

  Pollutant discharges can affect not only the health, behavior, and survival of individual
  organisms, but they can also adversely influence the vital interactions and energy flow of the
  food web.  This could lead to an adverse change in the structure or function of a population
  or community. When energy and materials flow from one trophic level to the next,
  contaminants in plant or animal tissues consumed are also transferred to the next trophic
  level.  If a contaminant is retained in the consumer's body tissues, its concentration will be
  higher in each succeeding trophic level, because an organism eats many times its own body
  weight during its lifetime. In this way certain pollutants can bioaccumulate as they travel up
  the food web, reaching toxic concentrations in the upper trophic levels of a food web even
  though concentrations in environmental media (e.g., soils, surface water) are relatively low.
  Methylmercury is an example of a bioaccumulative compound.  Methylmercury is generally
  present in small amounts in surface waters. It is absorbed directly from the water by aquatic
  organisms, but, more importantly, it bioaccumulates as it is passed up the food web,
  beginning with algae and ultimately passing to fish-eating animals such as gamefish and
  certain mammals, including humans. Mercury concentrations in consumers near the top of
  the food web can reach toxic levels, thousands of times greater than that of the ambient
Given the discussion above of interactions within ecosystems, it should be clear that defining the
boundaries of an ecosystem for purposes of assessment can be difficult.  Margalef (1968)
suggested that an investigator might operationally define ecosystem boundaries as locations
where energy flows are near zero or negligible in comparison with energy flows within the
system (Suter, 1993).  Examples of ecosystem boundaries by this definition would include
coastlines, forest edges, or watersheds. This definition is consistent with hierarchical
descriptions of ecosystems, where components within the system are strongly coupled with each
other and form systems or subsystems that are weakly coupled to other subsystems (Suter, 1993;
Hoekstra, 1992). A similar definition of ecosystem boundaries might be constructed using
nutrient cycles instead 3.3   VALUED ECOLOGICAL ENTITIES

Over the course of many years and activities, EPA has examined the issue of what environmental
entities should be considered priorities for protection.  EPA's (1997) Priorities for Ecological
Protection: An Initial List and Discussion Document for EPA states:

Environmental legislation has a long history of protecting certain groups of animals such as
fish, shellfish, migratory songbirds and waterfowl, and large mammalian game species. More
recently, legislation has sought to protect entire ecosystems and to ensure their "integrity" for
the foreseeable future.

                                                                                  Page 43

-------
The following paragraphs describe what is meant by ecological integrity and what characteristics
of ecosystems are diagnostic of ecological integrity.

3.3.1  Definitions

Ecological integrity has been defined by EPA (1994a) as "the interaction of the physical,
chemical, and biological elements of an ecosystem in a manner that ensures the long-term health
and sustainability of the ecosystems." This definition encompasses the concepts of
sustainability, resiliency., and biodiversity (U.S. EPA, 1997).

Sustainability is the ability of an ecosystem to support itself over a long time. In the context of
human use of resources, the concept indicates the ability of an ecosystem to support itself despite
continued harvest, removal, or other types of losses. For example, the National Marine Fisheries
Services uses measures offish reproduction, growth, and recruitment to determine allowable fish
harvests.

Resiliency is the ability of an ecosystem to adapt to or to recover from a stress. The stress might
be natural (e.g., flood, fire, pest outbreak) or anthropogenic (e.g., timber harvest, chemical
releases, development of land). A system subject to a permanent alteration will not return
exactly to its original state.  Resiliency is a natural  attribute of most undisturbed ecosystems,
reflecting the natural stresses (e.g., drought, temperature extremes, cycles in population
abundance) to which the ecosystem has adapted over evolutionary time. However, human
activities often move such stresses beyond the range found naturally and beyond the level of
resilience developed by the ecosystem during its evolution.

Biodiversity has been variously defined.  One useful definition is that of Norse (1990), who
describes biodiversity  as "the variety of life on all levels of organization, represented by the
number and relative frequencies of items (genes, organisms, and ecosystems)." Biodiversity is
one of the keys to an ecosystem's sustainability and resiliency. Ecosystems that contain more
species and include higher levels of genetic variation within species often are better able to
recover from disturbances than other ecosystems. This is because biodiversity tends to reflect
internal structural and  functional redundancies in an ecosystem, such that the  loss of some
individuals or species is compensated for to some extent by other individuals  and species (U.S.
EPA, 1997).

3.3.2  Identifying Valued Ecological Entities

Publicly valued ecological functions, services, and entities are evidenced by current  laws, by
private and government actions, and by expressed human values and philosophies. The values
range from immediate human utility to values that are independent of humans. At one end of the
spectrum are utilitarian values include the use of natural or manmade resources for direct human
consumption and in  the marketplace.  Somewhere in the middle are recreational and aesthetic
uses and human-derived preservation values.  At the other end of the spectrum are those
associated with moral, religious, and spiritual values (U.S. EPA, 1997).
                                                                                  Page 44

-------
For EPA, several statutory provisions direct EPA's attention to several specific ecological
concerns.  These include ecosystem components, ecosystems, and special places (U.S. EPA,
1997):

•       Ecosystem components: The Clean Water Act (CWA) specifies fish, shellfish, and
       wildlife as entities for protection.; the secondary National Ambient Air Quality Standards
       (NAAQS) under the Clean Air Act specifies soils, water, crops, vegetation, animals,
       wildlife, etc. as entities for protection..

•       Ecosystems:  The Clean Air Act (CAA) refers to "regionally representative" and
       "critical" ecosystems, and the CWA specifies rivers, lakes, and estuaries.  The CAA
       gives the Administrator the authority to assess risks to ecosystems from criteria
       pollutants.

•       Special places: The  CWA and CAA identify the Chesapeake Bay, the Great Lakes, and
       Lake Champlain.  The CAA also makes special provisions for national parks and
       wilderness areas.  The CWA identifies "Outstanding Natural Resource Waters" for
       enhanced protection.

In its discussion document for Priorities for Ecological Protection, EPA (1997) has proposed
four criteria for prioritizing ecological entities to be protected (see Chapter 3): mandated
protection, other societal values, rare or under threat, and ecological significance.

Mandated protection: Protection for certain types of entities is mandated by law (e.g.,
endangered species are protected by the Endangered Species Act; fish, shellfish, and wildlife by
the Clean Water Act; and special places such as the Great Lakes by the CWA and CAA).  These
laws codify some of the indirect use and non-use values that humans place on ecological entities.

Other societal value: As evidenced in its laws, practices, and community projects, society
values organisms, places, ecosystems, and their structures and functions for commercial,
recreational, spiritual, or other reasons.  Economic assessments regularly address commodities
that are used in commerce (market) and the recreational (non-market direct-use) values of
ecosystems. Although techniques to monetize indirect-use  and non-use values of ecological
entities are not yet available, these values can be addressed at least qualitatively in the economic
assessment.

Rare or under threat: Species need not be designated as threatened or endangered to be at risk
of local or regional extinction.  Many species of both plants and animals are declining or are
already so rare that some additional stresses might easily lead to their extinction.  An example is
neotropical migrant songbirds. Although few of these species are federally designated as
threatened or endangered, populations of most species in this group  are declining as their
habitats in both the northern  and southern hemispheres are degraded, fragmented, and lost.
Even rare species contribute  to overall biodiversity and can provide  functional redundancies
within ecosystems, contributing to resilience. Economic valuation of the protection of rare or
threatened species, communities, and ecosystems can be  achieved through the economic
valuation of biodiversity.
                                                                                   Page 45

-------
Ecological significance: Ecological entities that help to sustain ecosystems include plants and
animals that provide a significant food base, promote nutrient cycling, assist in regenerating
critical resources, or through competition or predation are "key" to maintaining the balance of
species in a community.  These are often referred to as "keystone" species or functions.  If the
ecological assessment team identifies potential impacts or benefits to keystone species, the team
should continue the conceptual model to include the important functional and structural
attributes of the ecosystem or community that might be affected by changes in the abundance or
presence of a keystone species.

In response to one of the recommendations of EPA's (1994b) report Managing Ecological Risk,
the Agency has begun a process of trying to reach consensus on a list of ecological concerns or
entities that should be considered in every EPA decision where relevant (U.S. EPA, 1997).
Exhibit 10, from EPA's (1997) discussion document Priorities for Ecological Protection,
provides the proposed list of ecological entities in three categories: (1) animals, plants, and their
habitats; (2) whole ecosystems; and (3) special places and species. For each entity, the table
provides examples of attributes of the entities that deserve protection.  The combination  of an
ecological entity and an attribute of concern for the entity represents an assessment endpoint.
Also for each entity, the table provides examples of the management objectives for each specific
ecological entity. Finally, each ecological entity is evaluated relative to the four criteria listed
above.
3.3.3  Neglected Benefits

Of particular importance to economic
assessments of ecological benefits is the entity
"ecosystem functions and services" which have
very high ecological significance, but values to
society that often are not recognized.

Biotic Resources

•      A species habitat is defined as the
       environment that a given species uses
       over the course of its life history.  It
       includes biotic (e.g., assemblages of plant
       and animal species) and physical (e.g.,
       rainfall and temperature range)
       components. For animal species,  suitable
       habitat is essential for both resident and
       transient animal populations.  Of
      "Neglected" Ecological Benefits

Biotic Resources
• Species habitat
• Biotic productivity
• Species fitness
• Food chain support
• Biodiversity
• Pest control
• Pollination

Processes/Infrastructure
• Microclimate control
• Geomorphological control
• Water supply
• Energy and nutrient exchange
• Purification of resources

Sources: U.S. EPA, 1993; Principe, 1995
       particular value is habitat for endangered, threatened, and rare species and habitat that is
       vital to important animal species activities (e.g., reproduction, foraging, migration,  and
       overwintering).

       Biotic productivity refers to the total amount of growth among organisms at any level of
       the ecosystem.  It includes primary productivity, which accounts for the growth of
                                                                                   Page 46

-------
       autotrophic organisms (primarily plants) that manufacture their own organic materials
       from inorganic sources.  Biotic productivity at all trophic levels is essential for energy
       transfer and for maintaining the integrity of natural food webs.

       Species "fitness" refers to the ability of a species to sustain its populations over the long
       term.1  Attributes that are closely related to species fitness include reproductive success,
       survivorship, and genetic diversity.  Genetic diversity within a species is needed to allow
       adaption of the population to changing environmental conditions.
       1 The more traditional use of the word "fitness" is to designate reproductive fitness, which is an
individual trait, not a species attribute.

                                                                                      Page 47

-------
a
H






M)
£
•^
«
s
=
.0
*W5
• pM
O
Q
o-
W

.S
•a
4*
."2
=
o
U
4*

o
.«

• PH
•^^
=
Ecological E
(M
O
+J
K
7 Proposed L
c\

o-
W














cS
'E

•+^
'S
u













"3 |
u S
•a J
"® '3
W
sc


L.
0
-d ^
— A
3 cu
€\ *•
£• 5
*3
CH



1 s
•g "^
® ^.
tfi


•d
"S
•d
e
S





•*-
O 3T,
Examples
objective



•*-
Examples o
attributes


Ecological
entity
L.
U

bp
^
"u
'"§
^^
fS





1)
a
0
t/3


i-H ^
O U
_r*  O '3 JH '3
a ft ft 2 ft
1 1 i ^ i
111 si




^ ."S ta
II!

r | |
0 §j "g
1||.^ ^
'5b"S " 2 -g -S .2
fll I— • K^, 'Zj ^_J t/J -f-J
_ j F— * K^ • ,-H qj Co
K ft '-S -d ^D H S
. O CS p! CS « cj1
(N ft d 3 ^3 -Ss cs
fl
1)
O !-<
«" 1

>1



5*
c3
^
^
O
s


H
^
3

^5


bb >-, "5
^ o 2

|-t^^
i/2 2 PQ  o
1 ^
C/3 '>

1>
tn "3
S o ^
^1
.5 "S .h
< "ftj

^3
bp
"?
S— H
>





^


•^r


fe-'u
> N
"3 bo
+j 0
0 u


"3
u
fl

 S 73
o .2 _8
a
O fo1
-a o
^ 8
                                                                                                                                                                   90
                                                                                                                                                                   TT
                                                                                                                                                                    O
                                                                                                                                                                    if.
                                                                                                                                                                    c«
                                                                                                                                                                   0.

-------
.•2  *
IS
 H
UJ




O/j
.^
«
S
=
• pM
O
Q
PH
UJ

•a
a>
a>
."2
=
o
U
^

o
.—
*^
=
W
'oil
"o
w
tJ
o
*M
1 Proposed L
c\
o\
PH
W











.5
u
•+^
'S
U











"3 |
u S
•a 2
O j""
1 «


L.
01
•d ^
— s
, b
cs
ft



1 1
* >



•d
S

•d
cs




^
O 3T,
£ s»
"5. -5
If
w



CM
Examples o
attributes


Ecological
entity
L.
So
-*^
U




bp




a
0
t/3


i-H
O
•gj 1"
] *""] ^





S
^H



0
"S
u
"x
l-a
CH °^
11


"S
"x
w


5. Wetlands
and stream
corridors
a
1 1
^ 8
i-H
F^ o
TH K*

ll




,_,
•^r


i-H
•M a
S °





o
C/2

a
^
O >i
-g o
a fe
ca bo
CH § ^
'3 "d j^


"S
"x
w

T3 ^
-g "S "o -a | ^
ra fe1 hh s ^:S
^ 8 ^|| |
_o
S
"3
bo




bp
|

^
"3
1§
£ s





s
J>H


Q

2
•d
fl CO
.a I
"S 3
la
•d
fl
Survival,
development,
reproduction, a
recruitment

•d
7. Endangere
species and
their habitats
1
a
s

bp




a
0



i-H
O
•gj 1"
S a


. §
60 ta ^
•^^ <
u^ <
a 03 r }
S
j/2 Q^ o


^*
"« oj1 ^O
(U . ^ -4—*
> Cd CH -(_>
l|||l
2 S o S "S3
« -3 ^ -3 tj
fli 03 • ^H c3 Jr;
X> d •— ( d ^
K S O S o

-------
       Food chain support refers to the support of the trophic structure of communities through
       adequate primary productivity and balanced predator-prey relationships that maintain the
       species diversity and abundance of organisms in each trophic level naturally associated
       with an ecosystem.  These relationships are essential for energy transfer and for
       maintaining the overall integrity of the food web.

       Preservation of biodiversity includes maintaining genetic diversity within populations,
       species richness within communities and ecosystems, and ecosystem variety within
       landscapes.  Biodiversity is generated and maintained in natural ecosystems, where
       organisms encounter a wide variety  of living conditions and chance events that shape
       their evolution in unique ways. Overall, biodiversity provides a reservoir for change,
       enabling life to adapt to changing conditions.

•      Pest control refers to natural pest control, which includes the control of pests by their
       natural enemies (e.g., predators, parasites, and pathogens), by genetic resistance in host
       plants, and by natural conditions or man-made environmental modifications (e.g.,
       fallows, hedge rows, flooding) that interrupt reproductive cycles of pest species,
       including weeds.  Natural pest control helps maintain the stability and diversity of
       ecosystems and reduces societal reliance on chemical pest control.

•      Pollination  refers to the dependence of many plants on insects or other wild animals for
       sexual reproduction (i.e., transfer of pollen). Successful pollination contributes to the
       overall maintenance of both plant and animal diversity in an ecosystem. Pollination is
       related to species habitat because the availability of pollinators can be affected by the
       availability of their foraging and reproductive habitats.

Process/Infrastructure

•      Microclimate control includes processes such as shading and wind breaking that
       provide local and regional temperature control.  Microclimate control is essential to
       maintaining the structure and quality of many wildlife habitats.

•      Geomorphological control describes the services that maintain the physical integrity
       and structure of ecosystems and wildlife habitats.  Specific processes include the
       following: organic production and export, sediment trapping, soil generation, flood
       control and desynchronization,  storm surge protection, wave and  wind buffering,
       shoreline anchoring, erosion control, and disturbance recovery.

•      Water supply includes  the quantity and quality of groundwater and surface water, which
       influence both the amount and quality of available aquatic habitat and characteristics of
       terrestrial vegetation.  For example,  groundwater recharge protects aquifers from
       saltwater intrusion in coastal areas, which otherwise could alter the species composition
       of the local plant, and therefore animal, communities. Terrestrial animals also rely on
       water for basic life support functions.
                                                                                    Page 50

-------
       Energy and nutrient exchange refers to processes that control the flow of energy,
       minerals, and nutrients (such as nitrogen, phosphorus, carbon, and sulfur). For example,
       photosynthesis by primary producers captures energy from the sun and converts
       inorganic carbon to organic carbon. Decomposition of dead biotic materials is essential
       to the provision of essential raw materials. These energy and nutrient exchange
       processes make energy and essential raw materials available to other organisms.

       Purification of resources includes the retention and detoxification of pollutants as well
       as the removal of excess nutrients. The retention and detoxification of pollutants can
       reduce  adverse effects on  survival, growth, and reproduction in wildlife.  The removal of
       excess  nutrients by microorganisms can maintain the integrity of aquatic ecosystems by
       preventing algal blooms and anoxic conditions where they do not occur naturally.

These neglected benefits can prove particularly useful in developing conceptual models for
economic assessments of ecological benefits, as described in Chapter 4.

3.4    TYPES OF ECOLOGICAL ASSESSMENTS

Ecological assessment is a process used to evaluate changes to ecological resources resulting
from natural or manmade events.  Ecological  assessments rely on the principles of ecology,
discussed above, to identify, describe, and estimate the consequences  of a change to any
component(s) of an ecosystem. The changes  may be biological (e.g., introduction of a nonnative
predatory species), chemical (e.g., presence of a toxic chemical), or physical (e.g., loss of
habitat). The ecosystem effects of the changes depend on those components of the ecosystem
that are directly impacted and interactions of those components with the rest of the ecosystem.

3.4.1  Assessment Models

Prospective (stressor-driven) and Retrospective (effects-driven).  Ecological risk/benefit
assessments can be used to estimate the likelihood of future adverse effects or improvements
(prospective) or to evaluate  the likelihood that existing effects are caused by past exposure to
stresses or removal of stresses (retrospective). Prospective risk assessments are stressor driven,
and prospective benefit assessments are driven by proposed management options. Retrospective
risk assessments are impact driven. For example, most watershed-level ecological risk
assessments have been  driven by  observations of loss of water quality and degradation of aquatic
communities, with the associated loss of recreational and fisheries values of the waters.
Retrospective benefit assessments could be conducted to determine the efficacy of actions taken
to help improve ecosystem condition.

Individual-level ecological risk or benefit assessments are used only for endangered species.
The ecological endpoints for assessing risks or benefits to such species include individual
survivorship, growth, health, and reproductive success.  This level of assessment ignores the rest
of the species in an ecosystem and higher-level ecological entities. This approach can be useful
in assessing threats or benefits to  endangered species in the context of actions that would affect
that species. Because individuals of endangered species are considered  valuable, this approach
generally looks for a threshold for individual-level effects rather than dose-response information.
                                                                                  Page 51

-------
This level of assessment generally misses ecosystem resources and services that should be
addressed in economic assessments of ecological benefits.

Population-level assessments can be approached from the bottom up using data on individual-
level endpoints in or from the top down by modeling interactions among species in a community.
The bottom-up approach uses individual-level endpoints, including mortality, growth, and
reproductive success, to model population growth or sustainability. The top-down approach uses
models of competition or predatory-prey relationships. Population-level assessment endpoints
include the number of organisms that can be harvested on a sustainable basis, population density,
and the probability of extinction. Where sustainable populations of a species are valued because
of their direct use (e.g., consumption) by humans, a population-level assessment is key to an
economic assessment of benefits.  Information on life  history strategies is important to
population-level assessments. As  Suter (1993) points  out, populations of long-lived vertebrates
(e.g., whales, seabirds) are more sensitive to changes in adult mortality than are shorter-lived
species (e.g., quail, grasshoppers) that produce large numbers of offspring at each reproductive
effort.  The shorter-lived species can be more sensitive to short-term catastrophic events that
coincide with and affect critical life stages (Suter, 1993).

Many approaches have been developed to conduct population-level assessments, including
modeling reproductive potential (e.g., using the "Leslie matrix"), aggregated models, and
individual-based models (noted above) using logistic growth or age-structured population
models (Suter, 1993, Gotelli, 1998). Aggregated models use aggregate components, such as
population size or adults and juveniles, to assess population-level effects.  These models are
simplified versions of models of age-structured populations, where age is divided into one or two
classes.

A difficulty with modeling population growth or harvest potential is that the factors limiting a
population (e.g., food resources or predation) often are difficult to identify  or measure in the
field (Suter, 1993).  Most populations exhibit density-dependent mortality and growth, which
complicates the modeling process. However, simple density-independent models have been used
successfully by fish and wildlife managers where time horizons are short and expected changes
are small (Suter, 1993). Gulland (1977) provides helpful discussions of surplus production
models and various stock-recruitment models developed by fisheries biologists.

Community-level  assessments focus on the interactions among species in the community,
including predator-prey and competitive relationships. These interactions can be much more
sensitive to a stress than the individual-level endpoints (e.g., mortality, growth, and
reproduction) used to estimate population-level effects. For example, chemical contaminants
might impair the ability of a prey species to detect (e.g., sensory impairment) or escape from a
predator (e.g.,  motor impairment) at levels that do not  otherwise affect the growth and
reproduction of the species. Many species interactions are of direct economic importance, such
as the predatory behavior of biocontrol agents and the symbiosis between legumes and nitrogen-
fixing bacteria (Suter,  1993). Assessment endpoints at the community-level include community
trophic structure and indices of community species composition (e.g., Index of Biotic Integrity,
IB I). Difficulties with community-level assessments include selecting the interactions on which
to focus and data availability. To the extent that an action or a stressor impacts the relationship
of some species with their abiotic environment, ecosystem-level assessments can be needed.

                                                                                  Page 52

-------
Ecosystem-level assessments use ecosystem properties, such as eutrophication, changes in
biodiversity, and net productivity, as the assessment endpoints. They also can be used to predict
changes in community or population-level endpoints (Suter, 1993).  For example, an ecosystem
model can be used to predict the effects of changes in populations at lower trophic levels on
species at higher trophic levels and changes in community structure that result.  Ecosystem-level
endpoints are needed to assess changes in many of the beneficial ecosystem services (e.g., flood
protection, water filtration, microclimate control). In general, ecosystem-level observations and
data are needed to  support stressor-response profiles for ecosystem-level responses. Relatively
few laboratories run such tests on toxic chemicals.  Stressor-response data for ecosystem services
tends to be derived from field studies in which parameter measures (e.g., areal extent of wetland
water recharge rate) are correlated with indicators of the ecosystem service (e.g., flood control).
A key uncertainty in using ecosystem-level stressor-response data in prospective risk/benefit
assessments is in extrapolating from the observed ecosystem to other ecosystems (Suter, 1993).

The most common practice in ecological risk assessments at this time is to predict ecosystem-
level responses from the bottom up, extrapolating from lower-level responses to the ecosystem
level. Because of functional and structural redundancies in ecosystems, significant effects can
occur in single species without affecting ecosystem structure or function. An ecosystem cannot
be more sensitive than its most sensitive component.  Thus,  it is a common practice in risk
assessments to identify thresholds for adverse ecosystem effects based on individual-level effects
on one of the most sensitive species. For example, EPA's National Water Quality Criteria
identify a threshold for adverse  ecosystem-level effects as the best estimate (fiftieth percentile)
of a concentration that would protect 95 percent of the species in the system (Stephan et al,
1985). Use of individual-level effects to predict a threshold for ecosystem-level effects is not
helpful, however, for the economic assessment of ecological benefits because it does not allow
estimates of the magnitude of response, i.e., it does not use exposure-response data to predict the
degree of change in response to an action of a specified magnitude.

Landscape-level assessments are needed where watersheds are at issue or where the geographic
distribution, connectivity, and diversity of different ecosystems or habitats over a large
geographic area can be affected by a proposed action. MacArthur and Wilson's (1963,  1967)
theory of island biogeography states that the  low species diversity characteristic of oceanic
islands reflects a dynamic equilibrium between rates of extinction and rates of colonization of
individual species' populations. This theory has been used to assess the effects of habitat loss
and fragmentation  in terrestrial environments on animal species, including neotropical migrant
songbirds, wolves, turtles, and many others.  Landscape-level assessments are also needed to
assess "edge effects,"  such as higher bird nest predation rates by blue jays and crows at the edge
of forests rather than in the interior of forests (Terborgh, 1989; Wilcove, 1985). Nest parasitism
by brown-headed cowbirds also occurs at the edge of forested habitats (Terborgh, 1989). Edge
effects can penetrate several hundred meters  into forested  habitats. Thus landscape-level
measures such as the ratio of the length of forest edge to the area of the forest interior can be
useful in predicting population-level responses of valued species.
                                                                                   Page 53

-------
3.4.2  Standardized Approaches to Ecological Assessments

Ecological assessments have been conducted under a variety of statutes by federal and other
agencies for some decades.  Standardized approaches and nomenclature for those assessments
have developed somewhat independently between the different agencies and offices.
Differences among the approaches can be attributed to different statutory requirements, the type
of information generally available at the start of an assessment, and the experience of the agency
or office responsible for the assessment.   The remainder of this section briefly describes the
primary different types of ecological assessments and explains why EPA's (1998) Guidelines for
Ecological Risk Assessment was used as the starting point for development of this Framework.

Types of Standardized Approaches

A variety of different "standardized" approaches to ecological risk and impact assessments have
developed over the past few decades in response to various legal mandates administered by
different agencies.  Key attributes of some of the more well-recognized approaches are listed in
Exhibit 11.

Ecological Risk Assessment.  As defined by EPA (1998), an ecological risk assessment is a
process that evaluates the likelihood that adverse ecological effects may occur or are occurring
as a result of exposure to one or more stressors. Ecological effects can be evaluated both
qualitatively or quantitatively in terms of structural and functional changes at one  or more levels
of biological organization.  In EPA's paradigm, the part of the ecosystem that is affected by the
change is called a "receptor(s)" and is usually a structural component.  The natural or
anthropogenic (i.e., manmade) event causing the effects is called a "stressor." Stressors can be
chemical, physical, or biological.  The "effects" of the stressor include direct changes to the
receptor(s) as well as indirect changes to other structural or functional components that are
affected through the interconnections that define the ecosystem (e.g., energy flows through the
food web).

Environmental Assessment (EA). An EA is frequently required under the National
Environmental Policy Act (NEPA), prior to, and in some cases, in lieu of, the preparation of an
Environment Impact Statement. EAs are concise documents prepared on a case-by-case basis by
government agencies. They describe the environmental impacts of a proposed government
action, provide a listing of agencies or persons consulted, and discuss possible alternative
actions. There must also be an evaluation of the probable cumulative, long-term environmental
effects including any beneficial impacts.

Environmental Impact Statement (EIS).  An EIS is a type of assessment that attempts to
reveal the consequences of a proposed action as an aid to governmental decisionmaking.  In the
United States, federal agencies are required by NEPA to prepare an EIS for any "major federal
action." Similar requirements exist for some states as well as for a few other nations.  The scope
                                                                                 Page 54

-------
                                        Exhibit 11
                 Standardized Approaches to Ecological Risk Assessment
Standard Name for
Assessment
Ecological Risk Assessment
(ERA): national-level
ERA: regional, landscape, or
watershed level
ERA: site-specific
Environmental Assessment
(EA)
Environmental Impact
Assessment (EIA)
Habitat Assessment (and
Habitat Suitability Index)
Hazard Assessment
Natural Resource Damage
Assessment (NRDA)
Statute
various, e.g.
RCRA, CAA
various, including
CWA
various, e.g.,
CERCLA, RCRA
NEPA
NEPA
NEPA and land
management
various, e.g.,
TSCA and FIFRA
CERCLA
Key Attributes
prospective/stressor driven, traditionally
chemical, now being adapted to other
stressors
prospective/stressor or impact driven,
usually chemical
prospective/stressor driven, usually
chemical
prospectiv/stressor driven, all types
prospective/stressor driven, predominantly
physical stressors
prospective/stressor driven, land
management changes
prospective/stressor driven, traditionally
chemicals
retrospective/impact driven, chemicals
only
Process
tiered
tiered
tiered
screening
refined
refined
screening,
and tiered
refined
Acronyms for Statutes: CAA - Clean Air Act; CWA - Clean Water Act; CERCLA - Comprehensive Environmental
Response, Compensation, and Liability Act; FIFRA - Federal Insecticide, Fungicide, and Rodenticide Act; RCRA -
Resource Conservation and Recovery Act; NEPA - National Environmental Policy Act; TSCA - Toxic Substances
Control Act.
and content of an EIS depend on the type of activity under consideration. An EIS is required to
predict any or all future effects on the environment. Consequently, it devotes considerably more
attention to identifying the full range of affected environmental components, defining the
geographic and temporal changes, and identifying secondary and tertiary effects than an EA.
NEPA explicitly states a policy of preserving the quality-of-life benefits of natural areas and
resources for future generations and evaluating cumulative impacts of activities over time.

Habitat Assessment. Habitat assessments evaluate the suitability of a local habitat to support a
given species. The most well known example is the U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service's Habitat
Evaluation Procedure (HEP).  HEP  provides a framework for determining habitat quality for
specific fish and wildlife species by quantifying many characteristics of the environment,
including physical, chemical, and biological characteristics (Scodari, 1992).  The relationships of
different values of those characteristics to the species' population densities and reproductive
success (implied suitability) have been developed from previous field studies. Use attainability
analyses performed under the Clean Water Act are also considered habitat assessments. They
determine what uses of a water body are attainable (e.g., swimming, fishing, water supply), the
                                                                                    Page 55

-------
extent to which pollution is impacting these uses, and the necessary pollution control measures
that are needed. Use attainability analyses must consider habitat limitations such as frequency of
low tides, natural water quality, and physical structure of the habitat.

Hazard Assessment. Hazard assessments determine the existence of a hazard. This type of
assessment identifies the types of effects a particular stressor might have on different groups of
organisms based on experimental exposures of organisms to the stresses. The hazard assessment
helps to identify particularly sensitive groups of organisms (or functions), which in turn affect
the selection of assessment endpoints. The phrase hazard assessment has been used to describe a
comparison of the magnitude of expected levels of stress in the environment to thresholds of
effect in groups of organisms (or functions).  Currently, that activity is more appropriately called
a screening-level ecological risk assessment.

Natural Resource Damage Assessment (NRDA). Natural Resource Damage Assessments are
retrospective assessments that address both ecological and economic damages.  Standard
methodologies promulgated by the Department of the Interior (DOT) and the National Oceanic
and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA) require an assessment of injury to an ecological
resource and an evaluation of the economic damages. In an NRDA, federal or state officials,
acting as trustees for natural resources, can seek compensation from responsible parties under the
Oil Pollution Act, CERCLA,  and other statutes for damages to natural resources (e.g., loss of
shellfish beds) caused by releases of oil and other toxic materials.  Trustees have used NRDA
regulations to seek monetary  compensation for natural resource  injuries associated with
accidental releases, such as the Exxon Valdez oil spill.  A NRDA may be conducted at a
Superfund site at the discretion of natural resource trustees. An injury  assessment, which
documents the adverse effects associated with a release, is the basis for the NRDA.  An injury
assessment is basically a retrospective risk assessment to link injuries to particular contaminant
sources.

Selection of Approach for this Framework

Of the various standardized approaches noted above, EPA's (1998) Guidelines for Ecological
Risk Assessment is the most general and flexible, because the Guidelines document was designed
to encompass the broad range of statutory requirements that different EPA  Offices administer.
Although historically, EPA has focused on assessments of chemical contaminants in the
environment, the Agency intentionally included information on  risk assessment for physical and
biological stressors as well to further broaden the scope and utility of the Guidelines within  and
beyond the Agency. That Guidelines document, for example, is general enough to be adapted to
benefit analyses (U.S. EPA, 1998).  That Guidelines document was developed by EPA's Risk
Assessment Forum over a period of years with substantial input from EPA  and other federal
agencies. Drafts of the proposed Guidelines received extensive  scientific peer review and
interagency committee review.  For these reasons, the framework described by EPA's (1998)
Guidelines for Ecological Risk Assessment was used as the starting point for building the
framework for the economic assessment of ecological benefits proposed in this document. The
adaptation of EPA's (1998) Guidelines for Ecological Risk Assessment io the ecological benefits
assessment addressed in this document is discussed in the next chapter.
                                                                                 Page 56

-------
The next chapter goes into more detail on conducting an ecological risk/benefit analysis.  The
purpose of Chapter 4 is to help the economist better understand the scientific framework for
analysis and type of information that may be generated through an ecological assessment.
Improved understanding of the ecological risk assessment process will facilitate communication
between economists and ecologists during planning of ecological assessments and thereby
increase the utility of assessment results for economic analyses.

References and Further Reading

Allen, T.F. and Hoekstra,  T.W.  1992.  Toward a Unified Ecology. Complexity in Ecological
Systems Series. New York, NY: Columbia University Press.

Briand, F., and Cohen, I.E. 1987. Environmental correlates of food chain length. Science 238:
956-960.

Brown, J.H.  and Lomolino, M.V.  1998. Biogeography.  2nd Ed.  Sunderland, MA: Sinauer
Associates, Inc. Publishers.

Costanza, R., R. d'Arge, R. de Groot, S. Farber, M. Grasso, B. Hannon, K. Limburg, S. Naeem,
R.V. O'Neill, J. Paruelo, R.G. Raskin, P. Sutton, and M. van den Belt.  1988.  The value of the
world's ecosystem services and natural capital. Ecological Economics 25(1):3-15.

Daily, G.C. (Ed). 1997. Nature's Services: Societal Dependence on Natural Ecosystems.
Washington, DC: Island Press.

Daily, G.C.,  S. Alexander, P.R.  Ehrlich, L. Goulder, J. Lubchenco, P.A. Matson, H.A. Mooney,
S. Postel, S. H. Shneider, D. Tilman, and G.M. Woodwell.  1997. Ecosystem services: benefits
supplied to human societies by natural ecosystems.  Ecological Society of America, Issues in
Ecology, Number 2, Spring 1997.

Gotelli, NJ.  1998. A Primer of Ecology, 3rd Ed. Sunderland, MA: Sinauer Associates Inc.

Gulland,  J.A.  1977. Fish Population Dynamics. London, UK: John Wiley & Sons.

Hairston, N.G. Jr., Hairston, N.G. Sr.  1993. Cause-effect relationships in energy flow, trophic
structure, and interspecific interactions. Am. Nat. 142: 379-411.

Hall, S. J.; Raffaelli, D. G. 1993. Food web: theory and reality.  In: Begon, M.; Fritter, A. H.,
eds. Advances in Ecological Research, Vol. 24.  San Diego, CA:  Academic Press; pp. 187-239.

Likens, G. 1992.  An Ecosystem Approach: Its Use and Abuse.  Excellence in Ecology, Book 3,
Ecology Institute, Oldendorf/Luhe, Germany.)

MacArthur, R.H., and Wilson, E.O.  1963. An equilibrium theory of insular biogeography.
Evolution 17: 373-387.
                                                                                Page 57

-------
MacArthur, R.H., and Wilson, E.O.  1967.  The Theory of Island Biogeography. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.

Margalef, R.  1968. Perspectives in Ecological Theory. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago
Press.

Norse, E.  1990. Threats to Biological Diversity in the United States.  Report prepared for the
U.S. EPA, Washington, DC, by Industrial Economics, Contract No. 68-W8-0038, Work
Assignment 115.

Odum, E.P., in collaboration with H.T.Odum.  1959. Fundamentals of Ecology. Philadelphia,
PA: Saunders.

Pimentel, D.  1988. Economic benefits of natural biota. Ecological Economics 25(l):45-47.

Pimm, S.L. 1980. Properties of food webs. Ecology 61: 219-225.

Pimm, S.L. 1982. Food Webs. New York, NY: Chapman and Hall.

Principe, P.P.  1995. Ecological benefits assessment: A policy-oriented alternative to regional
ecological risk assessment. Human and Ecological Risk Assessment l(4):423-435.

Scodari, P.  1992.  Wetland Protection Benefits. Draft Report. Prepared for U.S. EPA, Office of
Policy, Planning, and Evaluation under Grant No. CR-817553-01. October.

Stephan, C.E., Mount, D.I., Hanson, D.J., Gentile, J.H.,  Chapman, G.A., and Brungs. W.A.
1985. Guidelines for Deriving Numeric National Water Quality Criteria for the Protection of
Aquatic  Organisms and Their Uses.  Duluth, Minnesota: U.S. EPA. NTIS No. PB85-227049.

Suter, G.W. II.  1989. "Ecological Endpoints." in Warren-Hicks, W.,  B.R. Parkhurst, and S.S.
Baker, Jr., eds. Ecological Assessment of Hazardous Waste Sites: A Field and Laboratory
Reference Document. EPA/600/3-89/013. Corvallis Environmental Research Laboratory,
Oregon.

Suter, G.W. II.  1993. Ecological Risk Assessment. Boca Raton, FL: Lewis Publishers.

Suter, G. W., Efroymson, R.A., Sample, B.E., Jones, D.S. 2000.  Ecological Risk Assessment for
Contaminated Sites. Boca Raton, FL: Lewis Publishers.

Terborgh, J.  1989.  Where Have All the Birds Gone? Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

U.S. EPA. 1992a. Framework for Ecological Risk Assessment Washington, DC:  U.S. EPA,
Risk Assessment Forum.  EPA/630/R-92/001. February.

U. S. EPA. 1992b. Biological Populations  as Indicators of Environmental Change.,
EPA/230/R-92/011.  Washington, DC: Office of Policy  Planning and Evaluation.
                                                                               Page 58

-------
U.S. EPA.  1993. Habitat Evaluation: Guidance for the Review of Environmental Impact
Assessment Documents. Prepared by Dynamac Corporation for the Office of Federal Activities
under U.S. EPA Contract No. 68-CO-0070.  January.

U.S. EPA.  1994a. Managing Ecological Risks at EPA: Issues and Recommendations for
Progress. Prepared by M.E. Troyer and M.S. Brody. Washington, DC: U.S. EPA. EPA/600/R-
94/183.

U. S. EPA.  1994b. Toward a Place-Driven Approach: The Edgewater Consensus on an EPA
Strategy for Ecosystem Protection. Ecosystem Protection Workgroup.  Washington, DC: U.S.
EPA. March  15 Draft.

U.S. EPA.  1994c. Backgroundfor NEPA Reviewers:  Grazing on Federal Lands. Prepared by
Science Applications International Corporation under U.S. EPA Contract No. 68-C8-0066.
February.

U.S. EPA.  1997. Priorities for Ecological Protection: An Initial List and Discussion Document
for EPA. Washington, DC: U.S. EPA. EPA/600/S-97/002.

U.S. EPA.  1998. Guidelines for Ecological Risk Assessment. Washington, DC: U.S. EPA.
EPA/630/R-95/002B.

U.S. EPA.  2000. Assessing the Neglected Ecological Benefits of Watershed Management
Practices: A Resource Book.  Prepared for the Assessment and Watershed Protection Division,
Office of Water by ICF Consulting.  Washington, DC: U.S. EPA. April.

Wilcove, D.S. 1985. Nest predation in forest tracts and the decline of migratory songbirds.
Ecology 66: 1211-1214.

Wilson, E.O.  and Bossert, W.H. 1971. A Primer of Population Biology.  Stamford, CT: Sinauer
Associates Inc. Publishers.
                                                                               Page 59

-------
 4.0  ECOLOGICAL RISK/BENEFIT ASSESSMENT	

 As indicated in Chapter 3, the framework used for an ecological benefits assessment in this
 document is based on EPA's (1998) Guidelines for Ecological Risk Assessment. This section
 describes the adaptation of that framework to build the proposed framework for the economic
 assessment of ecological benefits.

 4.1    OVERVIEW OF EPA's GUIDELINES FOR ECOLOGICAL RISK ASSESSMENT

 An ecological risk assessment determines the likelihood, potential nature, and magnitude of an
 adverse ecological effect resulting from exposure to a stressor (U.S. EPA, 1998).  Some
 examples of ecological stressors are listed below:

                                          Biological

       Erosion                             .     Disease-causing organisms (Pfiesteria,
       Heat.  .                                   diatoms)
       lurbidity                           .     Genetically-engineered microorganisms
       Impoundments                      .     Non-native species (kudzu, zebra
       Habitat alterations                         mussels)

 Chemical

 •      Hazardous substances (e.g., pesticides, industrial wastes)
 •      Salinity
 •      Air pollutants (CO, NOX, ozone, hazardous air pollutants )


 The description of potential ecological effects should include magnitude, duration, spatial
 distribution, time to recovery, and other relevant parameters. As indicated in Chapter 3,
 ecological risk assessments may be predictive (i.e., estimate the probability and magnitude of
future ecological changes in response to a given stressor), or they may be retrospective, (i.e.,
 assess the probability that a past event caused this present problem).  A predictive benefits
 assessment may take the form of modeling the effects of an activity (e.g., removal of a stressor),
 such as the effects of reducing atmospheric nitrogen levels on the Chesapeake Bay.  Such
 assessments depend on applying previously collected data from similar events and ecosystems to
 a new situation. In a retrospective ecological benefits assessment, an effect may be well defined,
 such as reduced sedimentation, but the potential of other environmental changes contributing to
 the improvement must be considered.

 Benefits can be expressed quantitatively (e.g., a probability, such as an 80 percent chance that a
 population  will not go extinct in the next 100 years) and/or qualitatively (e.g., low, medium, or
 high).  In addition, the uncertainty associated with the probability needs to be addressed, either
 quantitatively or qualitatively.
                                                                               Page 60

-------
Steps in an Ecological Benefits Assessment

As illustrated in Exhibit 2 of Chapter 2, an ecological benefits assessment starts with planning.
During planning, the environmental decision makers, risk assessors, economists, and others
determine the need for and scope of the ecological benefits assessment. It is during this stage
that societal and political issues are considered, and a key to success is determining the
involvement of different individuals in planning the risk assessment.  Participants in the planning
phase may include risk assessors (including scientists), risk managers (e.g., government
regulators), economists, and, if appropriate, interested outside parties (e.g., environmental and
industry groups, those whose land may be affected by risk assessment decisions, state and/or
local government officials, etc.). Collaborative planning can help foster a consensus on which
ecological benefits are most valuable to the stakeholders  and the goals, scope, and timing of the
ecological benefits assessment.
                          Stakeholder Involvement in Planning

    Waquoit Bay provides an excellent example of how stakeholder involvement can be
    instrumental in developing management goals for an ecological risk or benefits
    assessment. It has been generally agreed by all involved parties that the Bay is changing
    — eelgrass is disappearing and is being replaced by thick mats of macro algae, fish kills
    are occurring, and scallops have disappeared.  Something must be done to prevent further
    degradation and restore what has already been damaged. Three steps were used to
    develop management goals for Waquoit Bay:

    •       A public meeting of all stakeholders;
           An evaluation of written goals by organizations having jurisdiction or an interest
           in the ecology of the  watershed; and
           A meeting of members of these organizations to review and approve the
           management goals.

    The public meeting was advertised in local newspapers. The meeting was designed to
    determine what the public viewed as valuable in the bay and what the main stressors
    were on these values. The participants found the bay to be valuable for a number of
    reasons including open space, scenic views, flyways for waterfowl, shellfishing,
    navigation, wildlife, and human serenity.  Stressors were many.  They included physical,
    chemical, and biological impacts to the  bay such as the introduction of non-native
    species, man-made noise, fertilizers, ignorant tourists, habitat loss, and boat wake
    disturbance.

    Numerous governmental (federal, state, and local) and non-governmental organizations
    were involved in the review  and approval of the management goals. The groups
    involved in developing these goals  are considered the risk management team for the
    watershed and will be principally responsible for implementing the management plan in
    Waquoit Bay.
                                                                                 Page 61

-------
Planning might be considered complete once the following objectives have been met.

       Objectives of the risk assessment have been defined (including criteria for success);

       Goals for ecological values have been established;

•      The range of options under consideration has been developed;

•      Focus and scope of the assessment have been agreed upon; and

       Resources to conduct the assessment have been provided (U.S. EPA, 1998).

As described in Chapter 2, EPA defines three phases for conducting ecological risk assessments
(U.S. EPA, 1998) that can be adapted for ecological benefits assessments:

•      Phase 1 — Problem Formulation;
•      Phase 2 — Analysis (exposure assessment and ecological effects characterization); and
•      Phase 3 — Risk Characterization.

A somewhat simplified diagram of EPA's risk assessment process is provided in Exhibit 12.
Readers interested in EPA's (1998) Guidelines as they pertain to risk instead of benefit
assessment are referred to that document. The remainder of this Chapter describes how those
Guidelines have been adapted to the proposed framework for economic assessments of
ecological benefits.

4.2    PHASE I:  PROBLEM FORMULATION
Problem formulation in
an ecological benefits
assessment is the process
for generating and
evaluating preliminary
hypotheses about what
benefits might accrue
from a proposed action
and its alternatives.  It
provides the foundation
for the entire economic
assessment of ecological
benefits. Problem
                  Problem Formulation Phase
Ecological
                Integrate Available Information
Develop Conceptual Models
Economic D
         Identify Endpoints and Linkages Between Them
       Prioritize Endpoints and Select Valuation Techniques
                            I
     Develop Analysis Plans, Ensuring Analytical Compatibility
                           Ecological Analysis Plan
                                     Economic Analysis Plan
                                                                                 Page 62

-------
formulation involves the development of three products: assessment endpoints, a conceptual
model, and an analysis plan.
                                                                                 Page 63

-------
                                     Exhibit 12
                       Ecological Risk Assessment Framework
   Planning
(Risk Assessor/
 Risk Manager
  Dialogue)
                     PROBLEM FORMATION
Assessment
 Endpoints
                    ANALYSIS
                                    AZ_
                        AZ_
                    RISK
                    CHARACTERIZATION
                     Risk
                   Estimation
                                                 Risk
                                              Description
                                    Communicating Results
                                     to the Risk Manager
                                       Risk Management
V
Characterization Characterization
of
of
Exposure Ecological


Effects






                                                                                Page 64

-------
The development of these products requires several activities:

•      Integrating available information;

       Using an iterative process and coordination between the ecological assessment team and
       the economic analysts to develop a joint conceptual model that links ecological
       assessment endpoint to economic benefit endpoints;

•      Prioritizing endpoints jointly with the economists; and

•      Developing the analysis plan, ensuring analytic compatibility with the economic
       assessment analysis plan.

4.2.1  Conceptual  Model

As described in Chapter 2, the ecologists develop their preliminary conceptual model based on
the cascade of ecological effects expected from the action itself to direct effects and indirect
effects.  The conceptual models presented in Chapter 2 are examples of preliminary models in
which little attention has been given as yet to what might be considered as assessment endpoints.
The ecologists and the economists work together in an iterative process refining the model to
ensure comprehensive coverage and appropriate linkages between ecological endpoints and
economic benefit endpoints.

In contrast to the goals of many site-specific ecological risk assessments (e.g., to protect an
aquatic community by protecting the most sensitive species in the community), a goal of the
economic assessment of ecological benefits is to capture as many of the potential benefits that
might result from an action as possible.  The emphasis in the benefits conceptual model is to
identify the full cascade of ecological effects that might result.  In developing the conceptual
model of likely ecological benefits, the framework described in EPA's  (2000) report Assessing
the Neglected Ecological Benefits of Water shed Management Practices can be helpful. The
report discusses linkages between watershed management practices and the neglected benefits
(see Chapter 3), including a general estimate of the strength of the linkages. Exhibit 13 below
provides an example of the neglected ecological benefits that can accrue from the forestry
management practices of revegetation and forest regeneration. Exhibit 13 also provides specific
examples of benefit endpoints within each category of neglected benefits.

The conceptual model is accompanied by hypotheses about how the initial action causes both
direct and indirect effects.  The complexity of the conceptual model depends on the complexity
of the problem (e.g., number and types of stressors, number of assessment endpoints, nature of
effects, and characteristics of the ecosystem).

A conceptual model diagram (see Exhibit  14) is a useful way to visually express the
relationships described by the benefit hypotheses.  Conceptual model diagrams can communicate
important exposure pathways in a clear and concise way, facilitating the coordination between
ecologists and economists in problem formulation. These diagrams and hypotheses also are
useful tools to aid communication with the environmental decisionmakers and interested parties.
                                                                                  Page 65

-------
The number of relationships that can be depicted in one flow diagram depends on the
comprehensiveness of each relationship.  The more comprehensive the relationship, the fewer
relationships that can be shown with clarity in one diagram, thus separate diagrams may be
required. There is no set configuration for conceptual model diagrams.

In developing the conceptual model, the ecologists can consider each proposed action in relation
to each category of neglected benefits, trying to identify and specify ecological benefits in that
category that might result from the proposed action.  Using the list of neglected benefits should
help to ensure that the ecological conceptual model is comprehensive and that as many
ecological benefits of a proposed action as possible are identified for the economic assessment.
Exhibit  14, illustrates where use of "neglected" ecological benefits in the conceptual model
helps to link the action to important and quantifiable ecological benefits.

                                       Exhibit 13
         Examples of Benefits Associated with Forestry Practice of Revegetation
                     and Forest Regeneration (from U.S. EPA, 2000)
Neglected Benefit
Category
Species Habitat
Biotic Productivity
Biodiversity
Food Chain Support
Microclimate Control
Geomorpholo gic al
Control
Water Supply
Energy and Nutrient
Exchange
Purification of
Resources
Example(s) of Benefit(s) Provided by Watershed
Management Practice(s)
• increase in species habitat provided by new trees
• contribution of new trees to primary productivity
• maintenance of aquatic plant productivity through decreased water column
and increased light penetration
turbidity
• maintenance of natural species assemblages by planting native species
• maintenance of or increase in biodiversity by increasing available forest habitat for
threatened or endangered species
• maintenance of species and population balance within food web
• increase in stream shading due to new trees in riparian areas
• maintenance of wind speed
• prevention of landslides and erosion by stabilizing soil
• decrease in soil erosion that could otherwise increase water turbidity and nutrient
loading
• preservation of soil microbes by maintaining leaf litter levels
• preservation maintenance of decomposition organisms in leaf litter and soil
• interception and retention of airborne pollutants
                                                                                 Page 66

-------
                                                Exhibit 14
                Conceptual Model for an Economic Assessment of Ecological Benefits
Action >
Stressor Reduction >
Primary Effect >
                                                     Improved Local Septic Systems
                                                       Reduced Nutrient Loading
                                               Reduced Eutrophication in Local Waters
"Neglected" Ecological
Benefits >
Secondary Effects;
Ecological Assessment
Endpoints >
"Neglected" Ecological
Benefits >
                   s
                        Increased
                        Shorebird
Tertiary Effects;     ^Populations*
Ecological Assessment
Endpoints >
Economic
Endpoints >
              Improved Aquatic Habitat
                 Increased Fish and
                Shellfish Populations
              Increased Use
              by Migratory
                 Birds
Improved Bird
  Watching
Increased Fish
  Landings
                        Improved Wetland Structure and
                                  Function
                             Increased Emergent
                            Vegetation Density and
                                Areal Extent
Improved Water
Filtration
^
Improved Water
Quality
1
r
Increased
Recreational
Swimming



Improved Storm
Protection

^
r
Reduced
Property Losses
    Key to Symbols:
                                                    Ecological
                                                    Assessment
                                                    Endpoints
   * Indicates assessment endpoints that might not be needed for an ecological risk assessment, but are added to assist
   the economic benefit analysis.
                                                                                                 Page 67

-------
4.2.2  Assessment Endpoints

The conceptual model of the ecological benefits assessment should include well-defined
assessment endpoints that will be linked to the economic benefit endpoints.  In the conceptual
models in Chapter 2, a series of vague endpoints were linked, with "improved wetland structure
and function" leading to improved water filtration and storm protection.  However, the concept
of improved wetland structure and function is too vague to allow quantitative links to those
benefits.  Thus, an assessment endpoint specified as "increased emergent vegetation density and
areal extent" was inserted to allow quantification.

Assessment endpoints may be defined for both structural and functional aspects of an ecological
resource at any level of organization ranging from a single individual to an entire landscape.
Exhibit 15 provides examples of assessment endpoints at different levels of biological
organization. Most benefit endpoints, however, are likely to be defined at the population level or
higher. This is true because a population is the lowest level of biological organization that can
be meaningfully protected (Suter, 1993). An effect on one or several individuals will not
necessarily result in significant population changes. Exceptions to this premise are threatened
and endangered species for which each individual is valuable to the survival of the population.
                                       Exhibit 15
                           Examples of Assessment Endpoints
Level of Organization
Individual
Population
Community
Ecosystem
Landscape
Ecological Entity
bald eagle
fish populations
aquatic
communities
lake
habitat
Assessment Endpoints
survivorship, reproductive success
population density, population growth rate
survival, development, and reproduction of
fish, aquatic invertebrates, and plants
eutrophi cation, nutrient flux
connectivity, ratio of length of edge to area
of interior, patch size
To assess interactions, it is important to use the most appropriate biological level of organization
at which the interactions can be observed.  For example, community-level effects can be
obscured at the ecosystem-level of observation, some ecological changes can only be effectively
evaluated from a landscape perspective, and so on.  Assessment using a population -,
community-, ecosystem-, watershed-, or landscape-level assessment may be most appropriate
depending on the situation.  For bioaccumulative compounds, exposure of the populations must
be traced through the food web in order to understand the full magnitude of potential impacts to
the community and ecosystem. The selection is based on the conceptual model on which the
assessment is based.  The conceptual model depicts the endpoints selected for assessment and
the interactions (or linkages) among endpoints.
                                                                                 Page 68

-------
Both structural and functional changes should be considered in a benefits assessment.
Improvements of a specific habitat, such as an increase in wetland acreage resulting from the
removal of a barrier to water flow, might yield both benefits that are both structural and
functional in nature.  In Exhibit 14, the conceptual model indicates that increased emergent
vegetation and areal extent can provide improved water filtration services and improved storm
protection because of the structural attributes of the emergent vegetation.

Criteria for Prioritizing Assessment Endpoints

As indicated in Chapter 2, there are both ecological and economic criteria that will be important
in prioritizing the potential assessment/benefit endpoints for quantitative assessment.  This
section focuses on the ecological criteria.
By addressing the needs for ecological
assessments under a variety of different
programs, the Agency has identified some
general criteria to assist in selecting and
prioritizing assessment endpoings.  EPA's
(1998) Guidelines for Ecological Risk
Assessment specify three criteria by which to
select assessment endpoints in a risk
assessment:  (1) have ecological relevance, (2)
be susceptible to the  stressor, and (3) and be
relevant to the management goals (see text
box). These criteria are particularly useful in
assessments of the risk of adverse ecological
effects. For an ecological benefits
assessment,  additional considerations and
criteria for identifying high priority
ecosystems and ecological components can
be useful. As described in Chapter 3, EPA
(1997a) has  proposed four criteria for
prioritizing ecological entities to be protected
in its discussion document for Priorities for
Ecological Protection:  mandated protection, other societal values, rare or under threat, and
ecological significance.  For a benefits assessment, it is more appropriate to consider these
attributes as prioritization criteria, instead of selection criteria. The remainder of this section
discusses EPA's 1998 criteria as they might apply to an ecological benefits assessment.

Ecological relevance.  The ecological relevance of an endpoint refers to its importance in
relation to other components of a specific community or ecosystem. For example, if the change
in abundance of certain benthic invertebrate species can affect the abundance or productivity of
fish in the community,  the benthic (i.e., bottom-dwelling) invertebrates are ecologically
important. As another  example, honeybees are ecologically significant in prairies because they
pollinate many plants.  Abundance  or age structure of a certain population offish may be
selected as an assessment endpoint because of the critical role the species plays in maintaining
the functional integrity of the ecosystem  (i.e., top consumer that exerts control over lower
  Example of High Priority Assessment
      Based on EPA's 1998 Criteria

Salmon abundance would rank high among
the possible assessment endpoints for
evaluating the benefits of not constructing a
hydroelectric dam on a river in the Pacific
Northwest. Salmon have ecological
relevance, because they are a food source
for many aquatic and terrestrial species, and
they eat many aquatic invertebrates.
Salmon are also sensitive to changes in
sedimentation, water temperature, and
substrate pebble size.  Most importantly,
salmon are valued by society as a source of
food, for recreational fishing, and for their
ceremonial and symbolic significance to
Native Americans.
                                                                                   Page 69

-------
trophic levels in the food web). Effects on primary producers, such as green algae in a lake, may
be critical to higher trophic levels, such as insect larvae, that feed upon the algae, and fish, that
feed upon the insect larvae.

Susceptibility to the ecological stressor. For an ecological risk assessment, EPA's (1998)
Guidelines indicate that an assessment endpoint must be based on a link between a susceptible
ecological component (or receptor) and exposure to an ecological stressor.  Susceptibility is
based on the sensitivity of the ecological receptor to the stressor and attributes of the life history
of the receptor that might influence the likelihood (and magnitude) of exposure. Some
organisms are more sensitive to stress at certain times in their life cycle such as during molting
or during seed germination. In conducting an ecological risk assessment, it is desirable to
determine effects on sensitive species and effects during sensitive life stages. For an ecological
benefits assessment that evaluates the benefits of removing stressors from the environment, this
criterion will be useful in selecting assessment endpoints.

In a benefits assessment, the susceptibility of the different types of receptors included in the
conceptual diagram need to be considered.  In addition, the potential for some changes to be
adverse while others are beneficial needs to be considered. For example, application of a
pesticide might kill the target organisms such as mosquitos in a stagnant pond (primary effect)
but it might also cause a decrease in the dragonfly population that feeds upon the mosquitos as a
primary food source (the dragonflies may starve or leave the area seeking food elsewhere).
Another factor to consider is that multiple stressors can increase the sensitivity of ecological
components to any given stressor. A seal with a virus may be weakened and thus  become easier
prey for a shark.

Relevance to management goals.  An ecological risk assessment is most useful when the
assessment endpoints are related to an ecological component or process that is valued by both
the public and decisionmakers such as clean air in parklands. An ecological benefits assessment
also requires that the economic benefit endpoints can be clearly linked to ecological endpoints.
Ecological benefit assessments should include those ecological components that are used  directly
by humans, such as sport fish, groundwater, or timber land. Ecological benefit endpoints might
also reflect those components and processes that indirectly benefit humans, such as water
filtration, climate control, or flood protection.  What is actually measured might be different
from what is important to the economic valuation study, but the relationship between the two
elements should be clearly defined. It also is important to remember that in many cases,
selection of an assessment endpoint is constrained by an environmental law, such  as the Clean
Air Act, or a policy goal, such as pollution prevention via water permitting.

Although not a specific criterion for selecting assessment endpoints, it is important that changes
to the assessment endpoint can be predicted or measured,  particularly if a stressor-response
                                                                                  Page 70

-------
       Linking the Assessment Endpoints to the Management Goals in Waquoit Bay

  The goal (or expected benefits) of the Waquoit Bay watershed management plan is to
  reestablish and maintain water quality and habitat conditions in the Bay to support diverse
  native fish and shellfish populations as well as reverse degradation of ecological resources
  in the watershed.  One way to help accomplish this is to reestablish viable eelgrass beds and
  associated aquatic communities in the Bay.  Therefore, an assessment endpoint was eelgrass
  abundance and distribution.  Eelgrass is a rooted plant in the shallows of the Bay that
  decreases erosion and increases sedimentation, which in turn, provides  food and habitat for a
  variety of marine organisms, such as juvenile scallops, invertebrates, and forage fish.

  Eelgrass is a good assessment endpoint because it has great ecological significance (i.e., it
  provides habitat for fish and shellfish.). The disappearance of eelgrass  might have resulted
  from reduced light due to shading by algal blooms and turbidity from suspended sediments.
  Stressed eelgrass beds are also more susceptible to disease from slime mold. In addition, its
  distribution and acreage covered can be readily measured.

  Scallop abundance in the Bay is not a good assessment endpoint.  Although it might have
  societal value, it would be difficult to assess whether changes in abundance resulted from
  natural variability or the effects of the stressor. A qualitative discussion of this endpoint
  might be useful, however, for benefits analysis.
relationship can be established.  If the assessment endpoint cannot be measured directly,
appropriate surrogate components or qualitative values will need to be identified as well as
methods for extrapolating effects to the assessment endpoints. For example, in many cases, a
stressor-response relationship could be impossible to quantify even though the existence of a
stressor-effect relationship is well established.  This is the case when an affected population
cannot be tested, such as an endangered species, or a situation where a synergist is involved. In
these situations, it may be appropriate to simply indicate that an effect has been observed without
indicating the intensity of the stressor.

Combining Ecological and Economic Criteria for Prioritizing Endpoints

In an economic assessment of ecological benefits, ecological selection or prioritization criteria
alone are insufficient for selecting the ecological assessment endpoints that will be examined
quantitatively. In addition, economic criteria, as described in Chapter 2, must also be
considered. When prioritizing endpoints for assessment, the ecologists and economists must
work together to agree to the relative importance of their respective criteria for the overall
assessment. The economic selection criteria include:

       Expected magnitude of the change in the economic value of one benefit endpoint relative
       to other endpoints;

•      Anticipated uncertainty associated with the predicted change and value of the change for
       the benefit endpoint relative to other endpoints;
                                                                                   Page 71

-------
       Variation in the change to each benefit endpoint under alternative policy scenarios; and

•      Analytical feasibility considerations.

Analysis Plan

In an analysis plan, the ecologists describe the data and measures that will be used to evaluate
the benefit hypotheses, i.e., the relationships between proposed actions and assessment
endpoints. Measures are identified for exposure, ecosystem and receptor characteristics, and
effects. Exposure can be quantified or qualitatively characterized (e.g., for chemical
contaminants, how much enters the environment and how it is distributed, including its possible
degradation or reaction products). Measures of ecosystem and receptor characteristics identify
important life history traits (e.g., reproductive cycles, migration patterns, and habitat types) that
affect the receptors' potential exposure or the response of assessment endpoints to the change in
the stressors. Measures of effects quantify the response of the receptors to changes  in the
stressors (e.g., survival, growth, reproduction, and community structure) and help link the effects
with the assessment endpoints.  The analysis plan also specifies how risks will be characterized
(e.g., qualitative vs. quantitative).

As indicated earlier, there are two aspects of an assessment endpoint, the entity (e.g., eelgrass)
and an attribute of that entity (e.g., spatial extent).  It is the latter aspect that must be measured
(quantitatively or qualitatively and directly or indirectly). Spatial extent of eelgrass can be
quantified by aerial photography; however, for some assessment endpoints, such as  songbird
population (an entity) and abundance (an attribute) as a result of pesticide ingestion, it may  be
difficult to estimate population losses due to mortality if the birds are able to fly away before
dying.
           Assessment Endpoints and Measures Specified in the Analysis Plan

  An ecological benefits assessment is to be conducted for adding a waste-water treatment
  process and sediment retention ponds at a pulp mill on a river in the Pacific Northwest.
  One assessment endpoint may be Coho salmon breeding success and fry survival.  Possible
  measures of the effects of reduced loading of toxic substances to the river on the fish may
  include: egg and juvenile response to low dissolved oxygen, response of adults to change in
  river currents and flow, and adult spawning behavior and egg survival in response to
  sedimentation and contamination.  Measures of the ecosystem and receptor (fish)
  characteristics include: water temperature and turbidity, abundance and distribution of
  breeding substrate, food sources for juveniles, variations in abundance, reproductive cycles,
  and laboratory tests for reproduction, growth, and mortality. Measures of exposure could
  include contaminant concentrations in water, sediment, and fish, and dissolved oxygen
  levels in the water.
As described in Chapter 2, during the prioritization of ecological and economic endpoints,
ecologists and economists will have discussed what information is required by the economist and
if that information can be derived from or developed during the ecological assessment. During

                                                                                   Page 72

-------
the analysis design phase, ecologists and economists formalize what information is needed by
economists and determine how and when that information will be provided. They must also
agree on how changes will be described or measured (e.g., from what baseline, under what
scenarios, at what level of spatial or temporal detail) and how any limitations or uncertainties
will be represented. In  addition, coordination is required to ensure analytic compatibility
between the  ecological  and economic assessments:

       The baseline from which effects are measured and the specific scenarios or policy options
       to consider must be consistent between the ecological assessment and the economic
       benefit analysis.

•      The analysis plans put in writing the assessment design, the analyses that will be
       conducted, data needs, measures, models to be applied, and statistical techniques to use.
       Both the ecological and economic analysis plans should specify what will be measured
       and how changes in endpoints will be expressed.

       The spatial area of consideration defined by the ecological benefits assessment serves as
       the starting point for defining the spatial limits of the economic analysis. It generally will
       be true that the spatial scale defined for the ecological analysis will be larger than the
       spatial scale at which the proposed actions can be described. Because the economic
       analysis focuses on human uses associated with ecological resources and humans are
       more mobile than plants and animals, the economic analysis might consider a broader
       spatial area than that defined by the  ecological assessment.

       Both the time horizon and the time step for analysis need to be compatible between the
       ecological and economic analyses. That requirement does not mean that they must be the
       same. For example, the time steps over which economic values of the  ecological changes
       are assessed could be shorter than the time steps over which changes in the ecosystem are
       assessed. It is important to account  for benefits for future generations in both
       assessments.

       The economic benefit's analysis should recognize the uncertainties in the ecological
       assessment process as well  as the uncertainties inherent in economic analysis. The level
       of uncertainty in the ecological benefit assessment process is often substantial because
       secondary and tertiary indirect effects are more difficult to estimate than primary or
       direct effects.

4.3    PHASE II: ANALYSIS PHASE

Once the analysis plan is complete and the ecologists and economists agree that the analyses and
measures will be compatible, the actual analyses can begin. In general, the ecological
assessment must be conducted first to provide the inputs on predicted changes in ecological
endpoints for the economic assessment. The ecological exposure and response assessments are
conducted by the ecological risk assessment team independent of the economists. In other
words, if problem formulation and planning for the analyses are done correctly, there should be
no need for communication between the economists and the ecologists during the ecological
                                                                                 Page 73

-------
analyses. Often, however, unexpected data gaps or unexpected interim modeling results might
require discussions between the ecologists and economists to resolve such issues.

The analysis phase consists of the technical evaluation of data to reach conclusions about
ecological exposure to the stressor and the relationship between the stressor and ecological
effects (U.S. EPA, 1998). During analysis, risk assessors use measures of exposure, effects, and
ecosystem and receptor attributes to evaluate questions and issues that were identified in
problem formulation.

The analysis phase is composed of two activities: characterization of exposure and
characterization of ecological effects (U.S. EPA, 1998).  These assessments are usually
conducted simultaneously, and interaction between the scientists conducting them is
recommended.
Exposure Assessment

Characterization of exposure in a
risk assessment identifies the
source(s) of the stressor, the spatio-
temporal distribution of the stressor
in the environment, and the contact
or co-occurrence of the stressor with
ecological receptors.  Many benefits
assessments will evaluate the
removal of a stressor from the
ecosystem; however, similar
analyses are required to estimate
which existing exposures might be
reduced or eliminated by a proposed
action. The exposure assessment
should identify the source of the
stressor and the complete pathway
by which it is acting upon the
receptor. A complete pathway
indicates that a stressor is released
from a source, is present at a level
that may cause an effect, and that the receptor is present and susceptible in the ecosystem and co-
occurs in time and space with the stressor. Exposure assessment may start with the source when
it is known, but in cases where the source is unknown, the analysis may attempt to link observed
contact of the stressor (e.g., a chemical contaminant) with the receptor (e.g., fish) to a source.
Contaminant residue levels in fish are examples of observed contact.

In addition to establishing the original or current source of the stressor, the stressor should be
described in terms of its distribution in time and space.  Several factors that may be considered in
describing a stressor include:
    Nitrogen Loading in the Chesapeake Bay

The Chesapeake Bay is eutrophic, with excess algal
growth causing declines in fish populations.  Several
possible sources of excess nutrients have been
identified:

       Atmospheric deposition
•      Run-off from agricultural land
•      Industrial waste streams

Although fertilizer runoff is the most obvious source
of the pollution, atmospheric deposition, which may
originate many miles from the watershed, has been
demonstrated to be a significant loading factor. Any
activity proposed to reduce nitrogen loading from
one of these sources should be evaluated in
conjunction with estimates of the loading from the
other sources.
                                                                                  Page 74

-------
      Intensity - How much of the stressor is in the environment and at what concentration or
      magnitude?  It may be necessary to determine the persistence of the stressor if the
      concentration is not the same at the source as it is at the receptor.

      Duration - Is the stressor present for a short time or an extended period of time, and how
      is the time defined (hours, days, years)?

      Frequency - Is the stressor occurring as a single event (chemical spill or volcanic
      eruption), intermittent (pesticide spraying twice a growing season), or continuous ?

      Timing - What is the occurrence of the stressor relative to biological cycles (e.g., if it
      affects reproduction, is it present during the breeding season or is it present when animals
      are in hibernation)?
                         Source of Stressors in Waquoit Bay

Multiple potential sources were identified for the many stressors acting upon the Bay.  Some
of the sources were local, others were regional.  Among the sources of the stressors to the
Bay are:

•      Cranberry cultivation, which releases nitrogen fertilizers, animal wastes, and
       pesticides;
       Local and regional atmospheric deposition of nitrogen and toxic contaminants,
       including mercury;
•      Residential development, which results in releases of nutrients from fertilizer and
       septic systems, habitat loss from housing and road construction, and altered
       groundwater flow due to increased impervious surfaces and the number of wells;
•      Industrial discharges to groundwater from a military installation;
•      Sewage treatment facilities and runoff of nutrients and contaminants entering the
       surface waters; and
       Marine activities that alter habitat, increase contamination, disturb sediments and
       shorelines, dredging, and increased fish and shellfish harvesting.

Thus to remove many of the stresses on the Bay, actions will be needed in many of the
community sectors. A screening-level economic assessment of the ecological benefits of
reducing the stresses might be conducted for the purpose of helping the local governments to
prioritize activities to reduce the stresses.
      Location - What is the physical area over which the stressor acts? The stressor may act
      over a very limited area (application of a pesticide in a specific area), or it may act over a
      large area (tropospheric ozone). What types of habitats are affected (e.g., nesting or
      spawning habitat).

                                                                                  Page 75

-------
Many stressors have natural counterparts (e.g., biogenic sources) or multiple sources.  The
characterization of these other sources can be an important component of the analysis. Whether
alternative sources are analyzed in a given assessment, however, depends on the objectives
articulated during problem formulation.

Describe the Distribution of the Stressor in the Environment

The spatial and temporal distribution of a chemical stressor(s) in the environment is described by
evaluating the pathways the stressors take from the source to the receptor (e.g., what is the
medium to which the stressor is released — air, soil, or water — and does it move from one
medium to another? For example, if a chemical is released to water, does it vaporize?). For
physical stressors that directly alter or eliminate natural habitats, the temporal and spatial
distribution of the changed environment should be described (e.g., for how many miles
downstream from the dredging is turbidity in the water column evident?). For biological
stressors, the distribution may be more complex.  These stressors have the ability to reproduce in
suitable environments, and do not necessarily rely on passive transport by wind, water, or gravity
to disperse or move to a suitable habitat.  Therefore, when identifying the exposure pathways for
biological stressors, both active and passive modes of dispersal need to be considered.
Furthermore, the ability of the biota to reproduce in favorable habitats can alter the relative
importance of alternate exposure routes.
                             Examples of Biotic Interaction

  Metabolism: Several bacteria have been genetically engineered to be particularly useful in
  degrading petroleum. These organisms are able to use petroleum as a food source and break
  down the oil to more environmentally benign compounds.  In some cases, metabolism of a
  compound may result in a toxic substance.  For example, inorganic mercury compounds
  may be metabolized by  microorganisms to methylmercury, which is very toxic.

  Bioaccumulation: Many chemicals that are lipophilic (fat-loving) such as polychlorinated
  biphenyls (PCBs), dioxins, mercury, and cadmium, are readily absorbed and are retained in
  fatty tissues. This way, these chemicals can enter the food chain and affect organisms that
  have been directly exposed.
The environmental fate of a stressor depends on several factors:

•      Distribution: Once in the environment, where does the stressor go? Stressors may be
       released to or formed from various environmental media.  A pollutant released to water
       may partition to the sediment, remain in the water column, or concentrate in the biota.
       Different physical forms of a stressor may partition to different media.

•      Transport:  When released or formed, a stressor may be transported from the source.
       Transport occurs via air, water, soil, or biological carrier.  Distribution and transport are
       closely related, and are frequently modeled to provide an estimation of where a stressor

                                                                                  Page 76

-------
       can be found in the environment. The physical, chemical, and biological characteristics
       of both the stressor and the receiving environment determine the transport and
       distribution of the stressor in the environment.

       Degradation or Transformation: Degradation may occur via biotic processes
       (metabolism), or abiotic processes (transformation by exposure to light or water).
       Degradation implies that a stressor is being physically changed into another simpler
       entity. Transformation may be a gradual or incomplete process (precipitation of a crystal
       from a complex solution). Degradation products and transformation products can also be
       toxic, perhaps more so. For example, elemental mercury released into the environment is
       transformed into methylmercury by microbes in certain aquatic environments.
       Methylmercury is more toxic than elemental mercury, and it is more readily
       bioaccumulated.

Identifying the distribution, transport, degradation, or transformation processes to which a
stressor is subject provides an indication to what extent the stressor is likely to act upon a
potential receptor. It may be possible to show that a stressor is unlikely to affect a receptor given
its environmental fate and transport.
The formation and subsequent distribution of
secondary stressors may be important depending
on the objectives of the assessment.  For
chemicals, the evaluation of secondary stressors
usually focuses on metabolites or degradation
products. Physical disturbance of the
environment can also lead to secondary
stressors. Several methods may be used to
understand the distribution and environmental
fate of a stressor and characterize the potential
exposure of specific receptors to the stressor.
Ideally, direct monitoring by collecting and
analyzing environmental (including biological)
samples is preferred. Monitoring should be
designed to define the area over which the
stressor may be acting and characterize spatial
and temporal variability in the level of stressor
(including its degradation products).
    Examples of Secondary Stressors

Chemical: Aldicarb is toxic to mammals
but not very persistent in the environment.
However, it is rapidly degraded to aldicarb
sulfone, which is toxic, very persistent, and
moves through the soil to the groundwater
where it may remain for years.

Physical: Dredging of a waterway not only
causes loss of habitat for the organisms at
the site of the activity, but may result in
severe turbidity of the water and excessive
sedimentation down-current.
Where monitoring information is lacking or difficult to obtain, models may be used to estimate
exposure to a stressor. Fate and transport models are commonly used to predict the amount that
is distributed over a geographic area or the amount of degradation that may be expected over a
period of time.  These models, preferably based on or verified by actual monitoring data,
generally use the physical, chemical, and biological properties of the stressor as well as the
environment of concern to characterize the exposure of the stressor to a receptor.  This
characterization should include spatial extent, intensity, frequency,  timing, and location of
exposure.  Typically, a combination of monitoring and modeling is  used to determine the stressor
levels.
                                                                                  Page 77

-------
Describe the Contact or Co-occurrence with the Receptors

The exposure assessment must also include an analysis of how the receptors are exposed to the
stressor (i.e., a pathway by which the stressor acts upon the receptor must be identified). In
many cases, it is not possible to establish direct causality due to the lack of appropriate
information. Therefore, it may be necessary to extrapolate or assume that a pathway exists.
However, if the analyst can demonstrate that a pathway from source to receptor is not plausible,
then it may be assumed that the receptor will not be affected by the stressor.

Characterizing the ecosystem on which the stressor is expected to have an impact will assist in
determining the nature and extent of exposure, and ultimately the adverse effects that may occur.
If a chemical affects only hardwood trees, but the surrounding area has only softwood trees, any
observed damage to the softwood trees is unlikely to be the result of the chemical.

Ecological components may be characterized in many ways, including:  habitat, predator/prey or
feeding relationships, reproductive cycles, and cyclic/seasonal activities. An important
consideration is at what level of biological organization should an assessment be conducted to
yield the most useful information?  Selection of the best level of organization for an assessment
must take into account many factors, including tools available for economic analysis if an
economic analysis is to be conducted. For example, a stressor may cause adverse effects in
many species in a community, and those effects may be exacerbated or reduced at higher trophic
levels, depending on the nature of the stressor. A classic example of an ecological stressor that
is best assessed at the community-lev el  is the bioaccumulation of DDT through the food chain.
Chapter 3 provides more information on the strengths and limitations of a benefits  assessment at
each biological level of organization.

It is also important to know the characteristics of the potential receptors. For example:

•      Are they present on a permanent basis (e.g., trees), or are they migratory (e.g., many
       species of birds)?

       Can and do receptors avoid exposure (i.e., are they capable of detecting the stressor and
       of movement to avoid it)?

•      What are population parameters, such as the size and distribution of the receptors?

•      Is the population particularly vulnerable (e.g., nesting  or molting) when exposure is most
       likely to occur?

       What are the most important physical and temporal parameters (e.g., seasonal and diurnal
       changes in temperature; does the lake freeze in the winter?)?

Exposure can be described in several different ways, depending on how the stressor causes
adverse effects:
                                                                                  Page 78

-------
•      Co-occurrence of the stressor with receptors. Co-occurrence is particularly useful for
       evaluating stressors that can cause effects without actually contacting ecological
       receptors.

•      Contact of a stressor with receptors.  Many stressors must contact receptors to cause an
       effect. For example, fish must come in contact with the bacterium Pfiesteriapiscicida
       before they become sick or die.

       Uptake of a stressor into a receptor.  Some stressors must not only be contacted, but
       also internally absorbed.  For example a chemical that causes liver tumors in fish must
       first be absorbed through the gills to reach the liver to cause the effect. Uptake can vary
       on a situation-specific basis, because it depends on the properties of the stressor (e.g., its
       chemical form), the properties of the receptor (e.g., its physical characteristics and
       health), and the location where contact occurs.

When the analyses and supporting documentation have been completed, the exposure assessment
should provide a description of the amount of the stressor that is in the environment, how it is
able to act on a receptor, and a characterization of the receptor that would or could be affected.

Exposure assessment is one of the more  difficult aspects of an ecological risk or benefits
assessment, and often introduces the largest uncertainties into the assessment.  EPA guidelines
and other reference materials on conducting exposure assessment, including the use of
probabilistic  methods, should be consulted (e.g., U.S. EPA, 1988, 1989a, 1989b, 1992, 1993a,
1997b, 1997c; Suter, 1993 ).

Effects Characterization

An ecological effects characterization describes the relationship between the stressor
characteristics (e.g., timing, frequency, magnitude,  spatial extent) and the magnitude of the
resulting ecological effects. The ecological effects  characterization indicates the levels of
exposure that elicit different responses (i.e., the stressor-response relationship). Many stressors
do not affect  all receptors in the same way.  In Waquoit Bay,  for example, nitrogen loading is a
significant stressor. Increased nitrogen levels in the Bay result in excessive algal abundance that
has two effects:  (1) shading of eelgrass by the algae, which prevents photosynthesis and kills the
eelgrass, and (2) decreased oxygen levels in the water that causes physiological stress,
suffocation, and increased predation on the finfish.  In this  case, there are several ecological
effects that can be attributed directly  or indirectly to nitrogen loading and that are expected to
reverse once  the nitrogen loading is reduced to more natural levels.  The ecological effects
characterization involves three steps:  determining (e.g., quantifying) the stressor-response
relationship(s), evaluating causality, and linking the measure of effects to assessment endpoints.

Determine the Stressor-Response Relationship

Once the receptors and stressors of concern have been defined and plausible exposure scenarios
have been identified, the next step is to identify those receptors for which stressor- response
information would be most useful for the ecological effects assessment. Stressor-response
analysis is often used for chemical stressors such as toxic substances. However, the technique

                                                                                    Page 79

-------
can be applied to many stressors and effects, such as increasing levels of microorganisms and
disease, increasing water temperature and enzyme inactivation, or habitat loss and reproductive
failure. This type of analysis is particularly valuable, because it describes effects as a function
of the level of stress. For example, a slight increase in temperature (stressor) in a given stream
may lead to a significant decline in trout abundance (response), but only a minor decline in algal
abundance.  If the temperature continues to increase, however, algae will also eventually decline
in abundance.
                       Measuring Stressor-Response Relationships

 It is difficult to determine whether algae are alive or dead. However, it is relatively easy to
 measure chlorophyll content both in the laboratory and in the field. Therefore, a change in
 chlorophyll content is often used to measure algal response to stressors, such as increased
 temperature, decreased light, or toxic chemicals.

 Certain types of pesticides are toxic to birds and animals, because they inhibit the enzyme
 cholinesterase, which is necessary for proper neurologic function. It is possible to establish
 a dose-response relationship between the amount of pesticide ingested and the effects of
 cholinesterase inhibition.  Relationships may range from changes in blood cholinesterase
 levels with no obvious nerve effects to relatively mild tremors to convulsions and death.
Stressor-response analysis often provides a quantitative characterization of the stressor and
effect. For an ecological benefits assessment where the expected magnitude of the change in
ecological assessment endpoints is needed, full stressor-response curves are needed.  In other
words, a single point on such a curve (e.g., a 50th percentile or 90th percentile response) is not
useful for benefits assessments.

Stressor-response relationships are not always linear (e.g., an increase in the stressor will not
necessarily result in an equal increase in receptor response). For some stressors, a threshold may
exist below which no response is evident.  For example, small increases in water temperature
may not adversely affect trout - growth may actually be enhanced - but progressively higher
temperatures will impair growth and, if high enough, result in death. Some stressors may have
disproportionate ecological effects if the receptors are already subject to another stressor. If deer
are starving because of deep snow covering their food, the introduction of wolves may reduce
the deer population by greater numbers than expected.

Stressor-response data are needed at the biological level of assessment, for example, at the
population level, the relationship between the stressor and a population-level measure such as
population density can provide an adequate basis for an assessment of population changes.  In
some cases, stressor-response profiles are estimated from measures at lower levels of biological
organization (e.g., individual level) based on models (e.g., various population models). For
some stressors, a quantitative characterization may be difficult to develop. In these cases, a
qualitative characterization may be used.  See Chapter 3 for more discussion on assessments
conducted at different levels of biological  organization. Stressor-response information is
typically obtained from laboratory or field studies.

                                                                                   Page 80

-------
Evaluate Causality
Without a sound basis for linking cause and
effect, the uncertainty associated with the
conclusions of the ecological risk
assessment is likely to be high.  For
example, many seal populations have
suffered from epidemics of a distemper-
like disease. While several causes
(stressors) have been suggested and
studied, including pollution-impaired
immune systems, warm ocean
temperatures, reduced food supply, and
pollution-impaired reproductive systems,
none have been definitively linked to
declining seal populations  (U.S. EPA,
1992b). Therefore, while the assessment
endpoint can be identified  for the receptors
(i.e., a change in seal abundance or
reproductive success), the  potential benefits
of removing any single stressor cannot be
quantified.

The following criteria may be used for
evaluating causality (U.S. EPA, 1998):

Criteria strongly affirming causality:

•       Strength of association
•       Predictive performance
       Demonstration of a stressor-
       response relationship
       Consistency of association
     Identifying Causes for Declines in
     Neotropical Migrant Bird Species

Populations of neotropical migrant bird
species appear to be in decline in many areas
of the United States.  These birds, such as the
Blackburnian warbler, eat insects and live in
the interior of large blocks of forest where
they breed. They migrate south in the winter,
following their food supply.

The risk hypothesis is that population decline
is caused by forest fragmentation in North
America and deforestation in tropical South
America. Forest fragmentation results in loss
of core forest areas and creation of additional
forest edge habitat which in which the
breeding success of the birds is lower due to
predation and parasitism by species adapted to
open and edge habitats.

Data (taken from previous studies) were
gathered to assess the susceptibility of
neotropical migrant species to edge effects,
island effects, and the loss of wintering habitat
in the tropics. Further monitoring was
recommended, including the development of
databases to collect additional data on these
birds.
                                                                                   Page 81

-------
Criteria providing a basis for rejecting causality:

•      Inconsistency in association
•      Temporal incompatibility
•      Factual implausibility

Other relevant criteria:

       Specificity of association
       Theoretical and biological plausibility

Link the Measures of the Effects to the Assessment Endpoints

Assessment endpoints express the environmental values of concern for a risk assessment, but
cannot always be measured directly. When the measures of effect differ from assessment
endpoints, sound and explicit linkages between the two are needed.

The following are examples of extrapolations that risk assessors may use to link measures of
effect to assessment endpoints (U.S. EPA, 1998):

•      Between similar organisms (e.g., bluegill to rainbow trout);
•      Between responses (e.g., mortality to growth or reproduction);
       Between different sources of data (e.g., laboratory to field data);
       Between geographic areas (e.g.,  northeastern U.S. to northwestern U.S.);
       Between spatial scales (e.g., stream to river); and
       Between temporal scales (e.g., data for short-term effects to longer-term effects).

During the development of the analysis  plan in the problem formulation phase (Phase I), the
ecological assessment team identified the extrapolations that would be required between
assessment endpoints and measures of effect. Decisions about specific extrapolations are usually
based on the scope and nature of the risk assessment, resources available for conducting the
assessment, and the amount of uncertainty that is acceptable. During the analysis phase, the
assessors implement these extrapolations.  However, they should reconsider all available data to
determine whether the plan should be modified. For example,  the exposure characterization may
indicate different spatial or temporal scales than originally anticipated. If a stressor persists for
an extended time in the environment, it  may be necessary to extrapolate short-term responses
over a longer exposure period and population-level effects may become more important.

The goal of the analysis phase is to provide sufficient information such that it is possible to
characterize the changes in ecological assessment endpoints specified during Problem
Formulation.
                                                                                  Page 82

-------
Characterizing Uncertainty

Uncertainty evaluation is an ongoing issue
throughout the analysis phase.  The purpose
of an uncertainty analysis is to formally
recognize that the ecological risk assessment
is constructed upon incomplete knowledge
and to explain the implications. Specifically,
the uncertainty analysis characterizes both the
qualitative and quantitative uncertainties
associated with the input values and carries
those uncertainties through to the estimated
exposure and ecological effects.

Any uncertainty analysis need not always be
expressed mathematically.  Instead, a
qualitative description may be used, such as
indicating that the animal tested may not be
the best surrogate for animals actually
exposed to  a stressor.  This frequently occurs
in wildlife toxicity testing where the
laboratory animal may be more or less
sensitive than other species in the wild.
           Uncertainty Factors

Uncertainty factors may be quantitative or
qualitative depending on their application.
In the development of a conceptual model
for the benefits assessment, there may be
uncertainty associated with the assumptions
used for the model.  Examples may be the
use of a well characterized species as a
surrogate for a species that is less well
characterized (e.g., use of coyotes rather
than wolves). A pathway may not be
clearly defined from the source of the
stressor to the receptor.  For example, a
species of bird exhibit impaired
reproduction. The initial risk hypothesis
was that loss of habitat from timber cutting
was responsible for the impairment.
Alternative hypotheses (e.g., the birds are
exhibiting reproductive effects as a result of
runoff from the timber cutting exposing
contaminated soil) also should be
considered.
Each of the extrapolations listed in the
previous  subsection also introduces
uncertainty.  Other sources of uncertainty in an ecological risk/benefit assessment include, but
are not limited to:

       Sampling variability;

•      Inability to obtain appropriate samples (this may be of concern if the organism is
       endangered or difficult to identify or collect);

       Lack of knowledge about combined effects of multiple stressors; and

•      Nonlinear behavior of complex systems.

Quantitative measures of uncertainty are often difficult (and sometimes impossible) to provide;
when this is the case, the assessors should try to characterize uncertainty in a qualitative manner
as completely as possible.  This ensures that economists, policy makers, and others who use the
results of the ecological risk assessment have a sense of the assessment's strengths and
weaknesses.

Methods for analyzing  and describing uncertainty associated with an ecological risk assessment
range from simple to complex and are beyond the scope of this document.  For further reading
                                                                                   Page 83

-------
on the topic of uncertainty analysis, see EPA publications (1992, 1997a, 1997b) and discussions
by Suter (1993) and Suter etal. (2000).

4.4    PHASE III:  RISK/BENEFIT CHARACTERIZATION
The final step in an ecological benefits
assessment is estimation and characterization
of the changes in the ecological assessment
endpoints specified by the conceptual model
and the analysis plan. In this step, the
characterization of exposure and
characterization of ecological effects (Phase
III - Analysis) are integrated to provide an
indication of the changes in the ecological
assessment endpoints and associated
uncertainty. For a benefits assessment, single
point estimates of risk (e.g., threshold for
effect) is not useful; the hazard quotient
approach is not applicable.  Instead, the risk
and benefit estimation should be based on the
entire stressor-response relationship and the
probability  of exposure,  and decided based on
the process models. In other words, the
ecological risk assessment team estimates the
likely degree of change in the assessment
endpoint from the probability estimates of
exposure-probability function and from the
stressor-response curves.
     Stressor-Response Relationships

Examination of a time series of indicators of
the health of the forests in the northeastern
United States suggested that gypsy moths
might be playing a significant role in the
observed decline in forest condition. To
estimate the costs and benefits of
controlling gypsy moths,  information on the
relationship between gypsy moth abundance
and forest condition was sought.  The
literature revealed that a small number of
gypsy moth larvae may cause minor damage
to the foliage on some trees. However, a
larger infestation can result in stunted tree
growth or even tree death if the larvae eat
enough leaves where trees cannot sustain
their photosynthetic requirements. The
density of gypsy moths can be directly
related to tree damage, up to and including
death.
Monte Carlo simulations or other probabilistic approaches for incorporating variability and
uncertainty can be used to estimate the probability of exposure at various levels.  The Team also
should attempt to provide uncertainty bounds on that estimate and the likelihood that actual
responses would be greater or less than those predicted.  This determination can be qualitative or
quantitative. For further discussion of probabilistic assessments, see other EPA documents
(1997a, 1997b).

Process models are mathematical expressions that represent our understanding of the
mechanistic operation of a system under evaluation. A major advantage of using process models
for a benefits assessment is the ability to consider "what if  scenarios, and to forecast beyond the
limits of the observed data that constrain risk estimation techniques based on empirical data. For
example, process models may be used to extrapolate from individual-level to population- and
ecosystem-level effects.  These models may also be of use in estimating indirect effects on the
assessment endpoints and the probable rate of recovery.  A variety of process models are
available for both terrestrial and aquatic ecosystems (e.g., RAMAS, Aquatox). Because process
models are only as good as their assumptions, they should be treated as hypothetical
representations of reality until appropriately tested with empirical data.
                                                                                  Page 84

-------
After the magnitude and likelihood of changes in the ecological assessment endpoints have been
estimated, the results are ready to supply to the economic analysts. The ecological assessment
team should characterize both the beneficial and adverse effects that could accrue from an action
so that the economists can estimate "net" benefits.  The ecological assessment team needs to
provide the economic analysts with full descriptions of the potential range in natural variability
that might be expected in the assessment endpoint and the uncertainties associated with their
estimates of changes to the assessment endpoints. Where the analysis plan called for
quantitative assessments of variability and uncertainty for specific assessment endpoints, the
ecological assessment team should provide quantitative estimates to the extent possible. For all
other assessment endpoints, the ecologists and economists agreed to pursue only a qualitative
assessment of variability and uncertainty.

There are several other parameters that must be addressed to characterize changes in the
ecological assessment endpoints with sufficient specificity to be used in the economic
assessment.  The magnitude of effect needs to be specified in terms of geographic coverage, the
degree of change per unit area, the probability  of changes of that degree or higher (or lower), and
the time-frame over which the change would be expected to occur. Again, quantitative or
qualitative error bounds should be provided for these parameter estimates.

This document has focused on the economic assessment of ecological benefits. The ecological
assessment team might have included assessment endpoints that were not going to serve as
inputs to the economic analysis.  The team would prepare and present these results to the
audience for which they were intended.

The next chapter discusses how economists define the value of changes in an ecological
assessment endpoint, and subsequent chapters  discuss the steps associated with economic
benefits analysis and the specific methods  for the economic valuation of ecological  benefits.

References and Further Reading

Bartell, S.M.; Gardner, R.H.; and O'Neill,  R.V. 1992. Ecological Risk Estimation.  Chelsea,
MI: Lewis Publishers.

Norse, E.  1990. Threats to Biological Diversity in the United States.  Report prepared for the
U.S. EPA, Washington, DC, by Industrial Economics,  Contract No. 68-W8-0038, Work
Assignment 115.

Noss, R.P.; LaRoe, E.T.; ans Scott, J.M. 1995. Endangered Ecosystems of the United States: A
Preliminary Assessment of Loss and Degradation.  Washington, DC: U.S. Department of the
Interior, National Biological Service.

Principe, P.P.  1995. Ecological benefits assessment: A policy-oriented alternative to regional
ecological risk assessment. Human and Ecological Risk Assessment l(4):423-435.

Suter, G.W. II.  1989. "Ecological Endpoints." in Warren-Hicks,  W., B.R. Parkhurst, and S.S.
Baker, Jr., eds.  Ecological Assessment of Hazardous Waste Sites: A Field and Laboratory
                                                                                  Page 85

-------
Reference Document.  EPA/600/3-89/013.  Corvallis Environmental Research Laboratory,
Oregon.

Suter, G.W. II. 1993.  Ecological Risk Assessment. Boca Raton, FL:  Lewis Publishers.

Suter, G. W., Efroymson, R.A., Sample, B.E., Jones, D.S. 2000. Ecological Risk Assessment for
Contaminated Sites. Boca Raton, FL: Lewis Publishers.

U.S. EPA. 1988. Superfund Exposure Assessment Manual.  Washington, DC: Office of Solid
Waste and Emergency Response Directive 9285.5-1; EPA/540/1-88/001.

U.S. EPA. 1989. Superfund Exposure Assessment Manual — Technical Appendix: Exposure
Analysis of Ecological Receptors. Athens, GA: Office of Research and Development,
Environmental Research Laboratory (December).  EPA/600/3-88/029.

U.S. EPA. 1990a. Ecosystem Services and Their  Valuation. Prepared by RCG/Hagler, Bailly,
Inc., for the Office of Policy, Planning, and Evaluation. Washington,  DC: U.S. EPA.

U.S. EPA. 1990b. Biological Criteria: National Program Guidance for Surface Waters.
Washington, DC: U.S. EPA. EPA/440/5-90/004.

U.S. EPA. 1991. The Water shed Protection Approach Framework Document. Office  of
Wetlands, Oceans, and Watersheds. Washington,  DC: U.S. EPA.

U.S. EPA. 1992. Guide lines for Exposure Assessment. Federal Register. 57: 22888-22938
(May 29).

U.S. EPA. 1993a. Wildlife Exposure Factors Handbook Volumes 1 and 11.  Washington, DC:
Office of Research and Development; EPA/600/R-93/187ab.

U.S. EPA. 1993. Guidance for Specifying Management Measures for Sources of Nonpoint
Pollution in Coastal Waters.  Office of Water.  Washington, DC: U.S. EPA.  EPA 840/B-92/002.

U. S. EPA. 1993. A Guidebook to Comparing Risks and Setting Environmental Priorities.
Washington, DC: U.S. EPA. EPA/230/B-98/003.

U.S. EPA. 1994a. Managing Ecological Risks at EPA: Issues and Recommendations for
Progress. Prepared by M.E. Troyer and M.S. Brody.  Washington, DC: U.S. EPA. EPA/600/R-
94/183.

U. S. EPA. 1994b. Toward a Place-Driven Approach: The Edgewater Consensus on an EPA
Strategy for Ecosystem Protection. Ecosystem Protection Workgroup. Washington, DC: U.S.
EPA.  March 15 Draft.

U.S. EPA. 1996. Waquoit Bay Watershed Ecological Risk Assessment Problem Formulation.
U.S. EPA. Review Draft.
                                                                              Page 86

-------
U. S.  EPA.  1997'a. Priorities for Ecological Protection: An Initial List and Discussion
Document for EPA. Washington, DC: U.S. EPA.  EPA/600/S-97/002.

U.S.  EPA.  1997b. Policy for Use of Probabilistic Analysis in Risk Analysis. Office of the
Administrator, Washington, DC. May.

U.S.  EPA.  1997c. Guiding Principles for Monte Carlo Analysis.  Risk Assessment Forum,
Washington, DC. EPA/630/R-97/001. March.

U.S.  EPA.  2000. Assessing the Neglected Ecological Benefits of Watershed Management
Practices: A Resource Book. Assessment and Watershed Protection Division, Office of Water.
Washington, DC: U.S. EPA.
                                                                                Page 87

-------
5.0  BACKGROUND THEORY ON VALUING CHANGES TO

      ECOLOGICAL RESOURCES	

This chapter discusses how economists define the value of an ecological resource and then
estimate the value of a change to such a resource. This chapter provides a basic introduction to
welfare economics as applied to the valuation of environmental changes — it is not, however, a
comprehensive review of welfare economics. References for further reading on the subjects
discussed below are provided at the chapter's end.

Subsequent chapters will discuss the steps associated with economic benefits analysis and the
specific methods for estimating benefits, applying the general concepts introduced in this
chapter.  Readers should be aware that subsequent discussions presume an understanding of
basic economic concepts (e.g.,  supply, demand).

5.1   WELFARE  ECONOMICS AND THE VALUE OF AN ECOLOGICAL CHANGE

Welfare  economics provides the theoretical basis for estimating the economic benefits of an
action. Welfare economists assess the value of an action based on its effect on the well-being, or
level of welfare, of humans.  Economic value is based on what people want — that is, their
preferences — and is measured  by examining how people trade-off different goods and services.
Economic theory is based on the assumption that the decisions people make regarding what they
choose to consume and what they choose to do  for activities reflect the values they hold for the
various goods and services available.

The anthropocentric perspective of welfare economics implies that the economic value of an
ecological resource depends on the value humans derive from the resource.  Some people take
affront to this basic premise of welfare economics, arguing that decisions should be based on the
broader values of community, the impacts to future generations, or the inherent rights of natural
resources (see for example, Sagoff, 1988). Nonetheless, welfare economic analysis provides
useful information for making decisions and presently serves as the basis for most
economic/policy analyses. For this reason, this document focuses on describing the basic
concepts and techniques of welfare economists.  Decisionmakers must, however, keep in mind
that a welfare analysis is just one approach among many for evaluating a change and should
consider other perspectives and information when making policy choices.

The type, quantity, and quality  of goods and services available to an individual determine the
individual's level of well-being, or level of welfare.  Some goods and services are produced by
industry  and purchased by individuals in markets, some are produced within the household, some
are provided by government, and some are provided by nature or ecological resources. (See
Chapter  6 for a discussion of the different types of goods and services provided by ecological
resources).

The condition of an  ecological  resource determines the type, quantity, and quality of goods and
services  provided by that resource. As a result, any action that affects an ecological resource,
such as an environmental regulation or natural resource management activities, will likely also
                                                                            Page 88

-------
affect the goods and services the resource provides, and subsequently the level of welfare of the
individuals who enjoy those goods and services. Typically, economists estimate the welfare
change associated with a policy or action using an "effect-by-effect" approach (U.S. EPA, 2000).
Under this approach, economists measure the change in welfare associated with the change to
each good and service provided by the ecological resource and sum these individual measures to
estimate total benefits.  The next section describes how economists measure changes in welfare.

5.2    MEASURING THE BENEFITS OF IMPROVEMENTS TO ECOLOGICAL
RESOURCES - THE CONCEPT OF WILLINGNESS-TO-PAY

The economic value of a good is determined by the maximum amount of something else (usually
money) that an individual is willing to pay to obtain the good.  This measure of economic value
is called "willingness-to-pay" (WTP). For an environmental improvement, WTP is the amount
an individual is willing to pay to obtain the improvement.  An alternative measure, "willingness-
to-accept" (WTA) is defined as the minimum amount of money an individual is willing to
receive in compensation to forgo a benefit,  such as an environmental improvement, they would
otherwise receive.

The choice between using WTP or WTA to value changes in environmental quality implies
different assumptions regarding the property rights of individuals experiencing the change.
Using WTP implies that polluting entities have a right to pollute, so the public must pay them
not to pollute. Using WTA implies that the public has  a right to a clean environment and must
be compensated for pollution. There also can be significant differences in the estimated value of
a change measured  in terms of WTP or WTA. One reason for this difference is that for an
environmental improvement, WTP is based on an individual's level of welfare without the
improvement, while WTA is based on the level of welfare achieved with the improvement. (See
Hanley, Shogren, and White, 1997 for further discussion of this issue).

Additionally, measuring economic value in terms of WTP also does not allow for the possibility
that certain goods may be "incommensurable" for some individuals, because their WTP is
constrained by their income level.  This constraint of welfare economics imposes an ethical
assumption that people will always be willing to substitute other goods for ecological resources.
Although WTA is typically the theoretically correct measure for estimating the benefits of
environmental improvements, WTP is more commonly used in practice because it is easier to
measure and estimate (U.S.  EPA, 2000).

For consistency with how goods and services are traded through markets  and comparability with
the estimated dollar costs of an action, economists measure the benefits of an action, such as a
regulation, in dollar terms using WTP. WTP values reflect individual's preferences for
exchanging goods and services.  Because preferences are likely to vary from one individual to
another, WTP values for a change to a particular good or service will vary from one individual to
another. The total social value of an improvement in a good or service is the sum of the WTP
across all individuals.

Although economists are most often asked to value the change in social welfare (measured by
WTP) associated with a change  in a particular good or  service provided by an ecological
resource, they will also sometimes be  asked to value the availability or existence of the

                                                                               Page 89

-------
ecological resource itself. For example, an economist might be asked to determine the change in
social welfare associated with the complete loss of a wetland and all the goods and services it
provides. In this circumstance, the economist will likely have to value the individual goods and
services lost separately and sum these benefit estimates. Alternative approaches that attempt to
estimate the total value of such a resource based on replacement cost or embodied energy (e.g.,
Costanza et al,  1997; Ehrlich and Ehrlich, 1997; Pearce, 1998; Pimentel et al., 1997) have been
discussed recently, but are not appropriate for an economic benefit analysis because the methods
are not grounded in economic theory (U.S. EPA, 2000).

5.3    How ECONOMIC BENEFITS OF  IMPROVEMENTS TO ECOLOGICAL
RESOURCES ARE REALIZED

The economic benefits of an action that affects an ecological resource depends on how the state
of the ecological resource influences the supply or consumption of the goods and services
provided or supported by that resource. In evaluating the economic benefits of an action
affecting an ecological resource, economists  consider two possible relationships between the
resource and the goods and services enjoyed  by society:

•      The ecological resource is an input to the production of a good or service, such that the
       state of the ecological resource directly affects the production (or supply) of the good or
       service; or

•      The state of the ecological resource is a characteristic of the good or service, such that the
       state of the ecological resource directly or indirectly affects the demand for (or value of)
       the good or service.

Ecological Resource as Input to Production

When an ecological resource serves as an input in the production of another good or service,
changes affecting the quality or state of the ecological resource can have direct impacts on the
production or supply of the good or service.  "Production" might consist of a natural or
bioeconomic process, or a man-made or industrial process.  For example, a change in the ozone
concentration in the air will affect the growth rate of plants and, thus, the productivity of
agricultural crops. Alternatively, an improvement in the water quality of a river that provides
water used for paper production may reduce the processing costs and, thus, increase the
productivity of the paper mill. That same change in the water quality of a river might also affect
the non-market recreational opportunities provided, or "produced," by the river. The effect of
the change in the productive process may be  realized through changes in the flow of a non-
market good or service, a change in the price of a marketed good or service, or a change in the
wage rates or earnings of workers in the affected sector.

The State of the Ecological Resource as Characteristic of a Good or Service

When the state of an ecological resource is a  characteristic of a good or service, a change in the
state of the ecological resource affects the demand for that good or service. For example, the
demand for recreational fishing days at a particular  lake is likely to change if the water quality of
the lake is improved.  Similarly, the demand  for hiking days or scenic views may increase as  a

                                                                                 Page 90

-------
result of an improvement in air quality that increases visibility. The change in demand may be
realized through increased number of visitation days, increased number of users, or increased
spending to make use of a good or service provided by the ecological resource.

5.4    ESTIMATING WILLINGNESS-TO-PAY

There are several techniques used to estimate WTP for changes to goods and services provided
by ecological resources. The technique employed depends on the type of good or service
affected. The techniques used by economists may:

•      Estimate demand and supply curves for the good or service in question;

•      Estimate demand and supply curves for a related good or service; or

       Estimate WTP based on other observations.

Market Goods and Services

The change in social welfare for a given change in the supply or price of a good and service that
is sold through a market is often approximated by the sum of predicted change in consumer and
producer surplus.  Consumer and producer surplus is represented as the area above the supply
curve and below the demand curve.  These surplus measures are standard and widely accepted
terms of applied welfare economics. Consumer and producer surplus is derived from market
data on how much of the good is demanded and produced in the aggregate at various price levels
and can be easier to estimate than individual WTP.

Although surplus measures do not, in general, provide a theoretically correct estimate of the
change in social welfare, they can provide a reasonably accurate estimate of social WTP for
relatively small price changes (Willig, 1976). The estimate  is less reliable, however, for changes
in the quality or quantity of goods and services. Nonetheless, measures of changes in consumer
and producer surplus are often used as indicators of the economic magnitude of impacts when
more precise measures are not feasible or practical.

Non-Market Goods and Services

The lack of markets and prices for many of the goods and services provided or supported by
ecological resources often makes it more difficult to estimate WTP for changes to these goods
and services. For goods and services that are not traded through markets, economists measure
changes in economic welfare, or WTP, based on changes in human behavior and the decisions
people make under different circumstances. Economic techniques for non-market goods and
services estimate individual WTP using either market information for related goods and services
(revealed preference methods) or direct statements of people's preferences (stated preference
methods). Individual WTP estimates are generally averaged and multiplied by the total number
of affected individuals.

Chapter 6 provides more information on specific methods for estimating WTP for market and
non-market goods and services.

                                                                                Page 91

-------
References and Further Reading

Braden, J.B. and C.D. Kolstad, eds. 1991. Measuring the Demand for Environmental Quality.
North-Holland, Amsterdam:  Elsevier Science Publishers.

Costanza, R. et al. 1991.  "The Value of the World's Ecosystem Services and Natural Capital."
Nature 387: 253-260. May.

Ehrlich, P. and A. Ehrlich. 1997. Betrayal of Science and Reason. Island Press, Washington,
D.C.

Freeman, A.M., III.  1993. The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values: Theory
and Methods. Washington, D.C.:  Resources for the Future.

Hanemann, W.M. 1991.  "Willingness to Pay and Willingness to Accept: How Much Can They
Differ?" American Economic Review. 81(3): 635-647.

Hanley, N., J.F. Shogren,  and B. White.  1997. Environmental Economics in Theory and
Practice. Oxford University Press, New York, New York. p. 362-364, 395-396.

Just, R.E., D.L. Hueth, and A. Schmitz. 1982. Applied Welfare Economics and Public Policy.
Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall,

Pearce, D. 1998. "Auditing the Earth." Environment.  40(2): 23-28.

Pimentel, D., C. Wilson, C. McCullum, R. Huang, P. Dwen, J. Flack,  Q. Tran, T. Saltman, B.
Cliff. 1997. "Economic and Environmental Benefits of Biodiversity." BioScience.  47(11):
747-757.

U.S. EPA. 2000. Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses. U.S. EPA, Office of the
Administrator. EPA/24/R-00/003. September.

Willig, R. 1976.  "Consumer Surplus Without Apology." American Economic Review 66(4):
589-597.
                                                                              Page 92

-------
6.0   ECONOMIC ASSESSMENT OF ECOLOGICAL

       BENEFITS	

The first section of this chapter discusses the various components or steps of an economic
assessment of ecological benefits ("economic benefit analysis"). The steps of an economic
benefit analysis described here are based on EPA's (2000) Guidelines for Preparing Economic
Analyses. Later sections of this chapter provide additional information on the types of economic
benefit endpoints that might be considered by an economic benefit analysis and the different
approaches available for estimating the economic value of those benefits.

6.1    COMPONENTS OF AN ECONOMIC ASSESSMENT OF ECOLOGICAL BENEFITS

As discussed in Chapter 2, there is an extensive planning phase that precedes the ecological risk
assessment and the economic benefit analysis. The decisions made during that planning process
regarding the nature of the decision under study and other criteria guide the economic analysis.
Of particular importance in designing and conducting the economic benefit analysis is a good
understanding of the type of information needed by decisionmakers and the nature of the
information that will be made available from the ecological risk assessment.

Following the planning phase, the economic benefit analysis begins. The economic benefit
analysis generally follows an "effect-by-effect" approach (U.S. EPA, 2000). As noted in
Chapter 2, under this approach economists estimate the benefits associated with the major effects
of a policy or action separately and then sum together the value estimates for the individual
effects to arrive at an estimate of the total benefits.

An economic benefit analysis can be broken down into four steps:

•      Identify and prioritize economic benefit endpoints

       Describe and quantify effects of the policy or action on the economic benefit endpoints

       Estimate the value of those effects

•      Summarize and present the results

The key elements of each of these steps are discussed below.  Chapter 2 discusses in detail the
opportunities for improving the economic benefit analysis by coordinating with the ecological
risk assessment team in each of these steps. Chapter 2 also discusses the variety of issues that
must be coordinated with the ecological risk assessment in designing an economic benefit
analysis: establishing the baseline from which changes are measured, measuring changes to the
economic endpoints based on the changes to the ecological endpoints, determining the
appropriate spatial and temporal scale for the analysis, and determining how uncertainty will be
treated. These discussions are not repeated here.
                                                                             Page 93

-------
6.1.1  Identify and Prioritize Economic Benefit Endpoints

The process of identifying and prioritizing the economic benefit endpoints affected by a policy
or action is described only briefly here. A more detailed discussion of this step is provided in
Chapter 2.

The identification and prioritization of relevant economic benefit endpoints involves:

       Developing a list of preliminary economic endpoints;

•      Linking changes to ecological resources to changes in the economic benefit endpoints;

•      Prioritizing the economic benefit endpoints for consideration by the benefit analysis; and

•      Determining how the economic analysis will assess the changes for high priority
       economic benefit endpoints.

Economists identify potential economic benefit endpoints by understanding the policy or action
under study, reviewing analyses of similar policies or actions, and working with the ecological
risk assessment team to understand what ecological changes are expected.Linking ecological
changes to changes to specific economic benefit endpoints involves extending the conceptual
model developed by the ecological risk assessment team to include the economic benefit
endpoints that are expected to be affected. As noted in Chapter 2, the ecological risk assessment
team can provide valuable assistance to the economists in determining how various economic
benefit endpoints might be affected.

Time and resource constraints generally require that the economic benefit analysis focus on fully
assessing and valuing changes to a limited number of endpoints. Each endpoint's consideration
priority is based on decisionmakers' needs, the expected magnitude of the predicted change to
that endpoint, the uncertainty associated with the predicted change and anticipated value of the
change, and the variability of the change to each benefit endpoint under different policy options.
This prioritization method ensures that important changes that typically are not amenable to a
monetary assessment are given equal attention by the benefit analysis. For the high priority
economic benefit endpoints, the economic analyst must determine how the changes to each
endpoint will  be analyzed — with a qualitative, quantitative, or monetized assessment of the
change. The choice of assessment method depends upon the relative need  for a dollar value
estimate of benefits, the availability of the necessary data and appropriate quantification and/or
economic valuation techniques, and the time and resource constraints of the economic benefit
analysis. (See Chapter 2 for an extensive discussion of these steps.)
                                                                                 Page 94

-------
6.1.2  Describe and Quantify Changes to the Economic Benefit Endpoints

Using results from the ecological risk assessment and information from other data sources, the
economist describes the changes to the ecological services and values affected (i.e., the
economic benefit endpoints) and provides information on the magnitude of the changes.  The
ecological risk assessment is responsible for estimating the likely changes to the ecological
resources. If care has been taken to coordinate during problem formulation (see discussion in
Chapter 2), the information provided by the risk assessment will be compatible with the needs of
the economic benefit analysis.

In addition to the information from the risk assessment, economists may collect additional
economic data to describe and estimate the effects and economic value of changes to the
economic benefit endpoints. For example, in describing the impact of a change to an economic
benefit endpoint, the economist might consider the estimated number of users of the goods and
services provided by the resource (e.g., number of fishermen, number of visitors, local
population, national population), the quantity of the good or  service provided or used (e.g.,
timber production, commercial fish landings), or some measure of the magnitude of the
ecological resource itself (e.g., acres, productivity).

A thorough qualitative, and when possible quantitative, discussion of the changes to the
economic benefit endpoints is an essential component of the  benefit analysis. For endpoints for
which a monetized assessment is not possible, the qualitative or quantitative assessment provides
a measure of the good or service's importance and the degree of change experienced under the
policy or action. For those endpoints for which a monetized  assessment is conducted, the
qualitative and quantitative discussion of the change that is valued supports the dollar value
generated by the benefit analysis. Some ecological improvements may also result in economic
losses. The net of positive and negative economic changes must be calculated in determining the
benefits of any action.

6.1.3  Estimate the Value of the Changes

There are a wide variety of techniques available to estimate the value or change in value of
specific attributes or services provided by ecological resources. In this step, the economist
selects the approach that is most appropriate given the attribute or service being analyzed, the
data available regarding the production or demand for the attribute or service, and the time and
resource constraints of the study. The most common approach used by EPA analyses is benefit
transfer, in which value estimates from one study are applied to another situation.

Regardless of the technique used to estimate the value of changes to the economic endpoints, the
benefit analysis must describe the source of the value estimate and the degree of confidence in
the estimate. This is particularly important when using benefits transfer because transferring a
value estimate to a new situation can only increase the uncertainty associated with the estimate.

Several different techniques may be used to estimate the benefits associated with changes to
multiple endpoints.  Although using multiple methods may provide more information on the
value of changes experienced by the economic endpoints, care  must be taken to avoid double-
counting of benefits. A careful understanding of the relationships  among the various endpoints

                                                                                 Page 95

-------
considered is important for identifying potentially overlapping benefits that could lead to double-
counting.

Many economic valuation techniques estimate the value or benefits associated with a change for
an individual person (i.e., individual willingness-to-pay (WTP)).  To develop an aggregate
estimate of the social benefits of an action, economists sum individual WTP for the action across
all affected individuals.  For many actions that affect ecological resources, some individuals will
benefit while other individuals may experience a decline in their individual welfare. For
example, while removing a dam might improve opportunities for kayaking and other Whitewater
activities, it might also result in the loss of a boating area behind the dam for water skiing and
fishing. In this type of situation, the benefit of the action is the net total of all gains minus all
losses in individual welfare experienced by members of society.

In aggregating benefits estimates across all affected individuals, each individual's WTP is given
the same weight in the summation.  As discussed in EPA's Guidelines for Preparing Economic
Analyses (U.S. EPA, 2000), an equity assessment and impact analysis may be conducted to
assess the impact  of an action on any populations of concern.

Typically, the economic benefit analysis will examine changes that occur over an extended
period of time (i.e., longer than a single year).  The economic benefit analysis, therefore, may
need to describe when these changes occur over the time period considered by the analysis as
well as summarize the value of the change over the whole time period.  The standard approach
for summarizing the value of changes that occur over an extended time period is to sum the value
of all changes over the time period using discounting. Discounting is commonly used to express
future costs or benefits in present monetary value.  The use of discounting and the choice of an
appropriate discount rate are complex and highly debated issues that are beyond the scope of this
document. Of particular concern is the potential effect of discounting ecological benefits on
resource conservation and intergenerational  equity issues.  References for additional information
on discounting are provided in Chapter 7.

6.1.4  Summarize and Present the Results

As discussed in Chapter 2, the results of the  economic benefit analysis will  include the
prioritized list of economic effects,  discuss the criteria used to select the economic endpoints
examined in detail by  the benefit analysis, and discuss how the economic value  of the effects was
assessed.  The monetary benefits estimated for some of the changes will be  accompanied by the
qualitative assessment of other benefits that  were not monetized.  If possible, the qualitative
assessment should discuss the potential magnitude of the economic benefits for  any priority
endpoints that are not accounted for by the quantitative and monetized assessment. The final
report should also discuss to some degree the other effects  identified that were deemed less
important to the economic analysis.

Finally, the results of the economic analysis must disclose any source of error in the analysis and
the potential impact of such error on the results. The presentation of results should identify any
possibility of double-counting of benefits, any limitations of the analysis, and any potential
imprecision and uncertainty associated with the benefit estimates.  The analyst should note
uncertainties in the ecological assessment that are relevant to the economic  assessment and

                                                                                  Page 96

-------
discuss how these uncertainties may be compounded.  In discussing the potential impact of any
source of imprecision or uncertainty, economists should discuss whether the analysis is likely to
over- or under-estimate the economic value of benefits.

The results presented also may include information and details that are needed for other
analyses. For example, an equity analysis may require information on the geographic
distribution of effects, the distribution of ecological effects and economic benefits across
different ethnic or economic classes of the human population, or the distribution of ecological
effects and economic benefits over time.
                                                                                  Page 97

-------
6.2    IDENTIFYING THE SERVICE FLOWS AND OTHER VALUES PROVIDED
       BY AN ECOLOGICAL RESOURCE
                                                  Exhibit 16
                                   Proposed Taxonomy of Goods and Services
                                        Provided by Ecological Resources

                                      Good or Service
There are numerous types of goods and services provided by ecological resources that have
economic value to some or all individuals in society (see Chapter 5 for a discussion on defining
the economic value of
ecological resources). This
section discusses the various
types of goods and services
and offers their taxonomy,
which may be useful in
developing a comprehensive
list of specific economic
benefit endpoints. The
proposed taxonomy  for
generally characterizing the
goods and services provided
by ecological resources is
presented in Exhibit 16.
Some of goods and services
provided by ecological
resources are obvious
because they are directly
used or enjoyed by society,
such as the fish provided by
a fishery, the timber/lumber
provided by a forest, or the
                               Non-Use Value
     Use Value
                                        Direct Use
               Indirect Use
                              Direct, Market
                              Good or Service
Direct, Non-Market   Indirect, Non-Market
 Good or Service      Good or Service
                                                                              Page 98

-------
swimming and boating opportunities provided by a coastal area. These types of goods and
services are defined as direct, market uses, when the good or service is bought and sold through
open markets, and direct, non-market uses, when the good or service is not bought and sold
through a market.

The direct, market uses of an ecological resource are typically the most obvious and most easily
valued goods provided by an ecological resource because price and quantity information for each
good and service is generally available. The direct, non-market uses of an ecological resource
may be readily apparent, such as recreational opportunities, although more difficult to value.
Valuation of changes to direct, non-market uses is more difficult because the goods or services
are not sold through markets, making it more difficult to obtain information on the "price" of the
service and the number of people enjoying the service (i.e.,  how many people benefit from the
resource through a specific use).

Ecological resources will also provide  some services and ecological processes that indirectly
benefit society.  For example, a coastal wetland provides  services as a wildlife habitat and fish
nursery, as a means for flood control, and as a filtering system for run-off waters. These types of
services, which are not bought and sold through markets, are referred to as indirect, non-market
uses.  Individuals may value these services even though they are not directly using the resource.
Sometimes these types of services can  be connected to  other activities that humans value and,
therefore, are valued through that relationship (see the discussion on identifying economic
benefit endpoints in Chapter 2).

Economists also recognize several different categories of non-use values.  As the term implies,
non-use values represent the value that an individual places on the ecological resource that does
not depend on the individual's current use of the resource. Existence value, for example, refers
to the value people place on knowing that a particular resource exists, even if they have no
expectation of using the resource.  Other examples of non-use values include bequest value,
which refers to the value people place on a maintaining a resource for future generations, and
altruism, or the value people place on maintaining resources that are important to their family
and friends.

As described in Chapter 5, the benefits of an action that improves a specific ecological resource
can be estimated by  estimating people's willingness-to-pay  (WTP) for improvements to the
various types of goods and services provided by the resource. For example, in estimating the
benefits of an action to improve the quality of a wetland area, one might consider that the
wetland area  serves as a primary breeding area for several species of birds. Therefore, one might
estimate the change in the value of bird watching and recreational fowl hunting to the individuals
using the area. To capture the total value or benefits of a change to a specific ecological
resource, one also needs to consider the value of its role in supporting the ecosystem and the
indirect benefits it provides to mankind. That is, one needs to also identify and evaluate the
indirect, non-market uses and non-use values associated with an ecological resource.
                                                                                  Page 99

-------
The economic benefit analysis should identify as many different goods and services (and values)
affected by the policy or action.  For example, if a policy is expected to improve ecological
resources that support various bird populations, the economic benefit analysis might consider
potential impacts on the following goods and services society derives from birds:

•      Food source (direct, market use);

•      Hunting, bird watching, and contributing to the aesthetic environment for hikers,
       campers, anglers, and other recreationists (direct, non-market use);

•      Component to an ecosystem that supports or provides other goods and services and
       contribute to maintaining biodiversity (indirect, non-market use); and

•      As an endangered species or to maintain the bird species for future generations (non-use
       value).

The following four subsections elaborate on the types of goods and services that might be
provided by an ecological resource and identify the economic techniques that might be
appropriate for estimating the economic value of changes to these goods and services.
                                                                                 Page 100

-------
6.2.1  Direct, Market Uses
Direct, market uses refer to those goods and services provided by an ecological resource that are
directly used by society and are bought and sold through the market system. Direct, market uses
primarily refer to those goods produced by an ecological resource that are consumed by humans
or serve as inputs in the production of other goods, such as food products, water, fuel sources,
and building materials. Prices and quantities produced for these goods and services are directly
observable.

For example, one benefit of a policy to improve air quality might be measured through the value
(i.e., change in welfare) of the increased productivity of commercial crops and timber
production. Similarly, the benefit of an action to improve water quality might be measured
through the value of the increased production of a commercial fishery (i.e., more fish caught and
sold).

It is important to remember, however, that the change in value of the  direct, market uses (e.g.,
timber, crops, or fish) provided by an ecological resource (e.g., air, water) may represent only a
portion of the total benefits of the change experienced by the ecological resource.

Examples of Direct, Market Uses Provided by Ecological Resources

Q     Food Source
       •       Fish (specific species) — commercial fishery
       •       Crops (specific type: corn, beans, apples, etc.) — commercial and home
              production
       •       Animal (fowl, deer, etc.) — commercial consumption
Ul     Building Materials
       •       Timber (specific species)
       •       Stone
                                                                                Page 101

-------
Page 102

-------
Q     Fuel
       •       Timber (specific species)
              Coal
              Oil
Q     Drinking Water Supply
       •       Ground water reservoir
       •       Surface water reservoir
Q     Medicine
Q     Chemicals/Minerals

Valuing Direct Market Uses

There are a number of market-based approaches that may be useful in estimating the value of
changes to a direct market use provided by an ecological resource. In most cases, a market-
based approach is used to estimate the demand and supply functions for the good or service. For
some market goods, such as commodity crops and timber, detailed general and partial
equilibrium models have been developed, which estimate demand and/or supply responses to
changes in productivity, prices, and other variables.  Impacts or changes to the ecological
resource that affect the quantity or quality of the goods and services provided by the resource can
be measured by estimating the change in the demand and supply functions resulting from the
change and measuring the welfare change or change in willingness-to-pay.

For relatively small changes that do not change the supply or demand for the good or service
provided by the resource, the change in the value of the goods and services provided by the
resource can be measured based on the increase (or decrease) in the quantity  of the good or
service provided and the market price of the good or service (see later section on estimating
benefits using market price and supply/demand relationships for additional discussion of this
issue). Other market-based valuation approaches, such as examining the cost of alternatives or
the spending to provide similar goods or services, may also be useful when price or quantity
information is not readily available. Although these second-best approaches can provide an
estimate of the magnitude of the potential benefits, they do not directly reflect welfare changes.

Specific techniques that can be used to value changes in market-based goods include:

•      Market-Price and Supply/Demand Relationships
•      Market-Based Valuation Approaches.
                                                                                Page 103

-------
6.2.2  Direct Non-Market Uses
Direct, non-market uses of an ecological resource include those goods and services that are
directly observed and used by humans, but are not sold or traded through an open, competitive
market. Direct, non-market uses include both consumptive uses (e.g., recreational fishing and
hunting) as well as non-consumptive uses  (e.g., bird watching or boating). Direct, non-market
uses are generally considered quasi-public/quasi-private goods because access or use of the
resource can be controlled but is often not strictly regulated and the benefit or value to one
individual does not affect the benefit or value to others up to a point (i.e., congestion reduces the
benefit/value to all users).

Examples of Direct, Non-Market Uses Provided by Ecological Resources

Q     Fishing
       •      Recreational Fishing (specific species, area)
       •      Subsistence Fishing (specific species, area)
Q     Beach Use (sunbathing, swimming, walking)
Q     Recreational Hunting (specific species) - for sport and/or personal consumption
Q     Bird Watching (general, specific species)
Q     Tourism
Q     Boating
Q     Hiking/Camping
Q     Animal Viewing, Photography, Feeding (general, specific species)
Q     Sightseeing
Q     Aesthetic Value
                                                                                 Page 104

-------
Valuing Direct, Non-Market Uses

These types of services are not bought and sold through observable markets and therefore, do not
have market prices associated with their use. For most of these types of goods and services,
however, the change in the quantity and/or quality of the service being provided is quantifiable
(e.g., increased number offish caught per fishing trip, increased number of beach or boating
days, increased chance of viewing wildlife).  Because these types of goods and services do not
have market prices, non-market valuation techniques must be used to estimate the implicit prices
for the goods and services provided by the resource. Some methods rely on the explicit
transactions (e.g., entrance or licensing fees, spending to protect a resource) or observed choices
that people make (e.g., travel decisions, home location) that are associated with the use of the
goods and services provided by the ecological resource.  These methods assume that people
demonstrate, or reveal, the value they place on a good or service through the choices they make.
Other methods rely on the responses of individuals using the resource to proposed choices or
questions regarding the value they place on their use of the resource.  In some cases, more
sophisticated techniques and models, which combine information on engineering  and biophysical
processes with economic information, are used to estimate ecosystem changes and impacts to
specific uses or services.

Specific methods that may be useful in valuing changes to direct, non-market uses include:

Revealed Preference Methods:

•      Hedonic Price Methodologies
•      Travel Cost Methodologies
•      Random Utility Models

Stated Preference Methods:

•      Contingent  Valuation
•      Contingent  Activity and Combining Contingent Valuation with Other Approaches
•      Conjoint Analysis and Contingent Ranking.
                                                                                Page 105

-------
6.2.3  Indirect, Non-Market Uses
Indirect, non-market uses of an ecological resource include those goods and services that provide
an observable benefit to mankind but are not directly consumed or used by individuals. Indirect,
non-market uses include many ecological processes that indirectly benefit mankind by
supporting other ecological resources, maintaining viable ecosystems, and protecting the local
environment. Indirect, non-market goods and services are usually public in nature because
access or use of the ecological resource cannot generally be excluded and any number of
individuals can benefit from the use of the ecological resource through these services without
reducing the benefits accruing to anyone else. These goods and services are not sold or traded
through an open, competitive market, although a community may pay for replacement or
substitute goods (often through taxes) that provide the same public services as provided by the
ecological resource.

Examples of Indirect, Non-Market Uses Provided by Ecological Resources

Q     Flood Control
Q     Storm Water Treatment
Q     Ground Water Recharge
Q     Climate Control
Q     Pollution Mitigation
Q     Wave Buffering
Q     Soil Generation
Q     Nutrient Cycling
Q     Habitat Value
Q     Biodiversity

Valuing Indirect, Non-Market Uses

These types of services are not bought and sold through observable markets and therefore, do not
have market prices associated with their use. Because these types of goods and services do not
have market prices, non-market valuation techniques must be used to estimate the implicit prices
for the goods and services provided by the resource.  Some methods rely on the observed choices
that people make that are related to the indirect, non-market goods and services provided by the
resource. These methods assume that people demonstrate, or reveal, the value they place on the
                                                                                Page 106

-------
goods and services provided by ecological resources through the choices they make. In some
cases, expenditures for replacement or substitute goods that provide the same public services as
the ecological resource may be used to estimate the minimum value of the indirect, non-market
services supported by the ecological resource.  Other methods rely on the responses of
individuals to proposed choices or questions regarding the value they place on the goods and
services provided by the  resource.

Specific techniques that may be useful in estimating the value of changes to indirect, non-market
uses include:

Revealed Preference Methods:

•      Hedonic Price Methodologies
•      Replacement/Alternative Cost
•      Avoidance Expenditures

Stated Preference Methods:

•      Contingent Valuation
•      Contingent Activity and Combining Contingent Valuation with Other Approaches
•      Conjoint Analysis and Contingent Ranking.
                                                                                Page 107

-------
6.2.4  Non-Market, Non-Use Values
Non-market, non-use values of an ecological resource are the values that individuals hold for the
resource unrelated to their current use of the goods and services provided by the resource.
Individuals may value the existence of the ecological resource or the availability of the goods
and services provided by the ecological resource although they do not directly consume or use
the resource themselves. Non-market, non-use values may stem from the desire to ensure the
availability of the resource for future generations, benevolence toward relatives and friends,
sympathy for people and animals adversely affected by environmental degradation, or a sense of
environmental responsibility.  Additionally, the specific non-use values associated with a
particular ecological resource may not be mutually exclusive: when asked directly, people are
unlikely to be able to separately identify the non-use values they hold  or distinguish between the
value they place on direct or indirect uses and their non-use value(s).

Examples of Non-Market Non-Use Values Provided by Ecological Resources

Q     Scarcity Value
Q     Option Value (although some consider this a use value)
Q     Existence Value
Q     Cultural/Historical Value
Q     Intrinsic Value
Q     Bequest Value
Q     Altruistic Value
Q     Philanthropic Value

Valuing Non-Market, Non-Use Values

These types of services are not bought and sold through observable markets and, therefore, do
not have market prices associated with their use. Because these types of goods and services do
not have market prices, non-market valuation techniques must be used to estimate the implicit
prices for the goods and services provided by the resource. Furthermore, by definition, the non-
use value associated with an ecological resource cannot be estimated based on observed actions
or choices made by individuals.  Thus, to estimate non-use values economists must rely on
people's responses to proposed choices or questions  regarding the value they place on certain
                                                                                 Page 108

-------
ecological resources (known as contingent valuation). Determining the total non-market, non-
use value associated with a change to an ecological resource is often difficult because the total
value depends not only on the value each individual holds, but also on the appropriate number of
such individuals to count in the valuation process.  Additionally, as discussed in the later
technique sections, the use of contingent valuation is very controversial and continues to be
refined by economists, sociologists and psychologists.

The following techniques are applicable for estimating non-market, non-use values:

•      Contingent Valuation
•      Contingent Ranking
•      Conjoint Analysis.
                                                                                  Page 109

-------
6.3    APPROACHES TO MEASURING RESOURCE VALUES

This section introduces the reader to the different types of approaches available to estimate the
economic value (i.e., change in social welfare or willingness-to-pay) of a change in the quality
and/or quantity of the goods and services provided by an ecological resource. Each valuation
method has a different approach to eliciting the value that society places on such changes. Most,
if not all, techniques require sophisticated econometric analysis to employ.

This section organizes and explains the general types of valuation techniques and discusses,
generally, what data might be required to implement each type of approach.  A framework for
understanding the similarities and differences between the techniques is presented, followed by a
brief description of each category of techniques.

More detailed descriptions of the individual techniques are provided in later sections.  The
information provided on the individual techniques is based on findings from the literature; the
reader is encouraged to independently evaluate any technique for their own use.  An additional
reference document, EPA's Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses (U.S. EPA, 2000),  also
reviews the various techniques available for benefits valuation.

Valuation Techniques

Valuation techniques can be grouped into four general categories according to the means by
which preferences are revealed and the process by which these preferences are translated into
monetary values (Mitchell  and Carson, 1989; Freeman, 1993). To determine into which
category a method falls, it is necessary to ask the following two questions:

1.     Does the  technique use data or observations from people acting in real-world situations
       (i.e., revealed preferences) or from people responding to hypothetical situations (i.e.,
       stated preferences)?

2.     Does the  technique yield monetary values directly (i.e., direct estimation of willingness-
       to-pay) or must monetary values be inferred based on a model of individual behavior
       (i.e., indirect estimation of willingness-to-pay)?

Exhibit 17 illustrates the matrix and the corresponding organization of the valuation techniques
available for developing original valuation estimates (Mitchell and Carson,  1989; Freeman,
1993). Benefits transfer analysis, which is not listed in the following table,  relies on the results
of previous analyses to develop a valuation estimate for a new policy case or study site.
Following the table is a discussion of the four categories of approaches and benefits transfer
analysis.
                                                                                 Page 110

-------
                                      Exhibit 17
                     Categorization of Valuation Techniques
                               Direct Estimation of WTP
                             Indirect Estimation of WTP
 Revealed Preferences
 Approach
Market Price/Quantity
(Estimated Supply/Demand)
Market Simulation Models
User Fees
Replacement Costs
Travel Cost Studies
Random Utility Model
Hedonic Studies
Avoidance Expenditures
Referendum Voting
 Stated Preferences
 Approach
Contingent Valuation Studies
Contingent Ranking
Contingent Activity
Contingent Referendum
Conjoint Analysis
Note: Benefits Transfer Analysis relies on estimates developed using one or more of the
       techniques listed in this table.

Direct, Revealed Preference Approaches

Direct, revealed preference approaches require data on real-life choices made by individuals
regarding their consumption or use of a particular good or service. These approaches assume
that an individual who is free to choose the quantity of good or service they desire at a specific
price will choose the quantity that maximizes their welfare (or benefits), given the constraints
placed upon them by the market (e.g., limited individual income, availability of substitutes and
other goods, limited availability of specific goods or services). Thus, these types of approaches
can only be applied for goods and services bought and sold through markets.  Competitive
market prices and production cost information, for example, can be used to estimate supply and
demand relationships, that can then be used to estimate the consumer and producer surplus
associated with the goods or services provided by a resource.  Alternatively, more complex
market simulation models might be used to mimic market conditions in an effort to determine the
value (or change in value) placed  on a good or service. Estimating market relationships for a
good or service requires, at a minimum, time series or cross-sectional data on the price of the
good or service, the quantity sold  and consumed, detailed cost and revenue information for
representative producers, as well as data on the environmental change affecting the supply and/or
demand for the marketed good or  service.

In some circumstances, market data may be useful in providing a lower bound estimate of the
value of a good or service. User fees, or the amount paid to use the services provided by the
resources at that site, indicate a lower bound  for the value that individuals place on the use of a
specific site.  The replacement cost technique infers the value of goods and services from the
cost of replacing the goods and services or of providing alternatives.
                                                                                Page 111

-------
Indirect, Revealed Preference Approaches

Indirect, revealed preference approaches rely on the relationships between the value placed on a
good or service not traded through markets that is affected by environmental quality and the
other real-world choices that individuals make.  These approaches typically require modeling of
these relationships to infer values for the non-marketed good or service. Because of the need to
model complex relationships in order to infer values for a specific good or service, these
techniques tend to have fairly significant data needs, which may include: price and quantity
information for consumption of related market goods and services; use or consumption
information for the good or service one wants to value; characteristics of the goods or services as
well as substitute goods and services; and characteristics of users.

Travel cost studies, for example, have been used to estimate the value of a particular recreational
activity, such as fishing, based on the time and expense required to partake in that activity.
Similarly, in using the avoidance expenditures approach, the cost of a particular event (or
benefits of preventing an event), such as flooding, is estimated based on current expenditures to
prevent or reduce the negative impact of the  event. Random utility models estimate recreational
demand by focusing on an individual's choice among substitute sites for any given recreational
trip. Hedonic property and wage models attempt to identify the value of environmental quality
implicit in purchasers' willingness-to-pay for property and in the monetary value placed on
working conditions, respectively. Referendum voting offers an individual a fixed quantity of a
good or service at a fixed price.  If the individual accepts the offer, it can be assumed that the
person values the resource by at least that amount.  Thus,  referendum voting data (e.g., approval
for new regulation or management scheme) can also be used to indicate the minimum value
placed on protecting the resources affected by the outcome of the vote.

Direct, Stated Preference Approaches

Direct, stated preference approaches, or contingent valuation approaches, involve asking a
sample group of people directly about the values they place on certain effects or changes.  Some
direct approaches used to determine an individual's willingness-to-pay for a specific
improvement include:

•      Asking each individual directly how  much they would be willing to pay to ensure or
       prevent a change;

•      Asking each individual whether they would be willing to pay some specific amount of
       money to ensure or prevent a change, varying the amount of money across the sample;
       and

       Conducting a bidding game with each individual to determine the maximum amount each
       would be willing to pay to ensure or prevent a change.

By aggregating over the sample, an analyst can estimate a demand curve for the specific change,
which can then be used to estimate total WTP for the change. Both the degree of environmental
change and the cost of the change can be varied in a contingent valuation analysis.  Contingent
valuation analysis requires conducting a survey of a representative sample of individuals affected

                                                                                 Page 112

-------
by the environmental change. Good survey design and implementation are critical to the success
of a contingent valuation analysis.  Unfortunately, these activities, as well as the analysis of the
resulting data, are typically very time and resource intensive.

Indirect, stated preference approaches

Indirect, stated preference approaches are also contingent valuation studies, except that the
individuals questioned are not asked directly about the value they place on a specific change.
Instead, individuals are asked to make a decision about another situation that depends or
otherwise relates to the value they would place on the specific change to be valued. The
responses to these questions are then used to draw inferences about the value of changes to the
non-market good or service of interest. For example, individuals may be asked:

•      To rank combinations of varying quantities or qualities of goods, including both market
       goods, which have prices associated with their use, and non-market goods, for which the
       analyst wants to estimate the value (Contingent Ranking); or

       To estimate the change in their current level of activity or use of a specific good or
       service under alternative scenarios in which the availability and quality of the good or
       service is varied (Contingent Activity).

Contingent ranking asks individuals to rank combinations of varying quantities and qualities of
non-marketed environmental goods and services as well as other marketed goods.  In a
contingent activity study, individuals are asked hypothetical questions about their level of
activity under alternative levels of availability and quality of an environmental good or service.
In a contingent referendum study, respondents are asked whether they would vote yes or no for a
policy or action that would impose a specific cost on them and provide or ensure a hypothetical
quality or quantity of an environmental service.  Values for the environmental goods or services
are then inferred from the choices made by the individuals.  Conjoint analysis uses data gathered
from survey respondents  concerning the relative importance of various features of a product to
determine the willingness-to-pay for a particular feature. For any of these indirect, stated
preference approaches, the data requirements and concerns will be the same as those associated
with the direct, stated preference approaches.

Benefits Transfer Approach

Benefits transfer analysis can often be used to estimate the value of a particular change when the
resources or time to conduct original research are not available.  Benefits transfer is also a
desirable approach in cases where good information already exists from previous studies of the
good or service in question, particularly when studies exist for similar types of locations and
resource users. This approach involves identifying other valuation studies of similar changes at
similar sites and using, or transferring, the value from the previous study(ies) to the new site of
concern. In some instances, additional data might be used to adjust the value estimate to better
suit the new situation or to correct for errors introduced in the original study. More advanced
benefits transfer analysis  involves transferring a benefit function, demand function, or valuation
model to a new study site.
                                                                                  Page 113

-------
Data Sources

In addition to selecting a valuation technique, it is also necessary to identify data sources that can
be used in the valuation of public goods and services.  Some of the data, such as the ecological
components affected, will come from the ecological assessment. Other data will  also need to be
obtained from other sources.  The type of data required depends upon which valuation technique
is chosen.  Data might include market data on the prices of various goods, data on the number of
users (e.g., the number of fishermen using a specific fishery), the quantity used (e.g., acres of
forests cut down in a given year's lumber production), or some measure of the ecological
resource itself (e.g., acres of wetlands). The individual valuation technique sections provide a
detailed discussion of the types of data required to implement each technique.

References and Further Reading

Braden, J.B. and C.D. Kolstad, eds.  1991.  Measuring the Demand for Environmental Quality.
North-Holland, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers.

Freeman, A.M., III. 1993.  The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values:  Theory
and Methods. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future.

Mitchell, R.C. andR.T. Carson.  1989.  Using Surveys to Value Public Goods: The Contingent
Valuation Method. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future.
                                                                                Page 114

-------
6.3.1  Market Price and Supply/Demand Relationships
                                                                         Revealed
                                                                        Preference
                                                                         Approach
The "market value" of a good or service that is conveyed through the market system is the price
placed on the good or service.  The price of a good represents the value of an additional unit of
that good, assuming the good is sold through an undistorted, perfectly competitive market (i.e., a
market with properly assigned property rights, full information, and no taxes or subsidies).
Market prices can be used to value small changes in the quantity of a good or service being
provided (i.e., small effects or  changes that do not affect the supply of or demand for the product
or service). For example, the value of increased commercial fish harvest in a specific bay could
be estimated based on the market value of the additional fish caught (i.e., pounds of additional
fish caught multiplied by market price per pound offish), assuming that the increased harvest for
the area under study will not affect the market price.

The value (i.e., cost or benefit) of larger scale changes that are likely to affect the supply or
demand for a good or service cannot be correctly valued using market prices. Using market
price ignores the change in the extra value provided by the good or service to consumers (e.g.,
the amount consumers would be willing to pay above the market price, known as consumer
surplus). For the same reason, the change in the total consumer expenditures for a good or
service (market price times the quantity purchased) is generally not a good indicator of the
benefits associated with a change in the use of that good or service. Where such a bias matters,
other approaches are necessary for estimating the benefits or the change in willingness-to-pay
resulting from a change in the goods or services provided by an ecological resource.

Estimating Supply and Demand Relationships

One approach is to estimate the supply and demand relationships for each service or product
before and after the environmental  change to estimate the benefits of a specific action.
Depending on the good or service considered, the change to the ecological resource will cause a
shift in the supply curve or the demand  curve. The change in the willingness-to-pay, or benefits,
associated with the action can then be estimated based on the change in the area above the
supply curve and below the demand curve. The demand and  supply curves, or functions, are
estimated using past data on prices and  quantities of the good sold, the cost of production inputs,
and information on production relationships (i.e.,  the quantity of output produced with a given
amount  of inputs).
                                                                                Page 115

-------
   Market Simulation Models

   Economists have developed market simulation models that combine economic,
   engineering, and biophysical information to estimate changes in market supply and/or
   demand relationships, and thus, the benefits, of an environmental change.  Such models
   can be used to examine the relationship between changes in environmental quality, such as
   the amount of acid deposition, and "material damage," including reductions in stocks of
   physical assets such as buildings, bridges, roads, and art, or changes in biological outputs,
   such as agriculture and vegetation.  Environmental changes that affect the level of output
   or production will affect the price and quantity of the good on the market that can lead to
   further changes in output or production. Although simple estimates of changes in supply
   and demand relationships can be used to estimate the initial change in price and quantity, a
   more complex market simulation model is needed to estimate further changes that result
   from market interactions and feedback relationships. Market simulation models are
   regularly used to estimate the effects of changes in environmental quality on agricultural
   and timber production. Simulation models have also been used in material damage
   assessments to identify changes in production and consumption caused by environmental
   changes, identify the responses of input and output to these changes, and identify the
   adaptations affected factors can make to minimize losses or maximize gains from changes
   in opportunities and prices (Adams and Crocker, 1991).
Valuing the benefits of a change to an ecological resource based only on a single or a few market
goods or services provided by that resource is unlikely to capture the full benefits of the change
because many other services provided by the resource that are not sold through markets may also
be affected. In the case of an action that improves the quality of a forest, for example, the forest
will provide improved habitat for other species of flora and fauna and better scenic views and
recreational opportunities, in addition to the increased value of the forest as a supply of timber.
Therefore, when using changes to market goods and services to estimate benefits, one should
also consider the potential benefits associated with additional services provided by the resource
that are not sold through markets.

       Advantages

X"     For established markets, price, quantity, and input cost information should be readily
       available.

V     Actual consumer preferences are measured using observed data.

       Disadvantages

X"     Market data may only be available for a limited number of goods and services provided
       by an ecological resource and may not reflect the value of all productive uses of a
       resource.

                                                                                 Page 116

-------
V     It may be difficult to correctly estimate demand and/or supply relationships if limited
       data on prices and quantities are available.

X"     It may be difficult to separate the supply and demand effects and to isolate the effects of
       the environmental change.

V     Market-based analyses do not capture non-use value.

Data Requirements

This technique requires time series data on market prices for the resource, the quantity sold and
consumed, and detailed cost and revenue information for representative producers, as well as
environmental data for both before and after the change.

References and Further Reading

Adams, R.M. and T.D. Crocker.  1991.  "Materials Damages," in Braden, John B.  and Charles D.
Kolstad, eds. 1991. Measuring the Demand for Environmental Quality. North-Holland,
Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers.

Braden, J.B. and C.D. Kolstad, eds. 1991. Measuring the Demand for Environmental Quality.
North-Holland, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers.

Freeman, A.M., III.  1993.  The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values:  Theory
and Methods. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future.

Haniey, N. and C.L. Spash. 1993. Cost Benefit Analysis and the Environment.  Brookfield,
Vermont: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.

Just, R.E., D.L. Hueth, and A. Schmitz.  1982.  Applied Welfare Economics and Public Policy.
Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall.

Loomis, J.B.  1993. Integrated Public Lands Management: Principles and Applications to
National Forests, Parks,  Wildlife Refuges, and BLM Lands, Chapter 6, Applying Economic
Efficiency Analysis in Practice:  Principles of Benefit-Cost Analysis. New York, New York:
Columbia University Press.
                                                                               Page 117

-------
6.3.2  Market-Based Valuation Approaches
                                                                         Revealed
                                                                        Preference
                                                                         Approach
Although the goods and services provided by an ecological resource may not be bought and sold
through the market, there may be other market transactions occurring that provide information
regarding the value of the environmental good or service under study. When estimating the
value of specific goods or services, for example, it may be useful to look at other market
transactions, such as fees paid for use of similar services or spending on projects or activities
designed to provide similar goods or services. When estimating the value of changes to an
ecological resource (or the goods and services it provides) it may be useful  to consider the
estimated cost of alternative actions undertaken to produce similar results or, alternatively, the
level of spending to prevent or reduce the negative impacts resulting from damage to an
ecological resource.

Although these measures cannot generally be expected to provide an exact measure of the
benefits of a change to  an ecological resource, they can be useful in developing preliminary or
order-of-magnitude estimates. This section describes how the cost of alternatives or
replacements, avoidance expenditures, simulated markets, referendums, and user fees might be
useful in estimating the benefits of improvements to ecological resources.

Alternative/Replacement Costs

The cost of providing or replacing the goods or services that an ecological resource could
provide can be used to  estimate the value of those goods and services and, in some cases, the
benefits of an action to protect or restore that ecological resource. This approach is based on the
concept of revealed preference: by choosing to undertake an action to provide or replace certain
goods and services, society demonstrates (or reveals) that it values the goods and services
provided by the ecological resource (and correspondingly value the resource itself) by at least as
much as the cost of the project.  In other words, it is assumed that if society invests in a project
to provide similar services to those provided by an ecological resource, then the value of the
services provided can be assumed to be at least as great as the dollar amount spent on the project.
Therefore, the cost of the project might also be used to approximate a lower bound for the value
of the ecological resource that provides the same services. Specific examples include:

       Using the cost of building a retaining wall to estimate the value of wave buffering
       services provided by a wetland or coastal marsh area;

•      Using the cost of fish breeding and stocking programs to estimate the value of fish
       nursery services provided by estuaries or upland streams; or

•      Using the cost of constructing and operating a storm water filtration plant to estimate the
       value  of water filtration by wetland areas.

In using this approach,  however, it is important to keep in mind that because the goods or
services replaced probably represent only a portion of the full range of services provided by the
ecological resource, this approach is likely to underestimate the benefits of an action to protect
or restore the ecological resource. In addition, this approach should  only be applied if the
                                                                                 Page 118

-------
project has been implemented or if society has demonstrated its willingness-to-pay for the
project in some other way (e.g., approved spending for the project).  Otherwise, there is no
indication that the value of the good or service provided by the ecological resource to the
affected community is greater than the estimated cost of the project.

In a similar context, the cost or estimated value of alternative approaches to achieving an
environmental goal (e.g., reduced pollution levels) can be used to estimate the value of changes
(most often improvements) to an ecological resource.  Under this approach, the estimated
benefits of one program designed to protect or improve an ecological resource would be used to
estimate the benefits of a different program that is also intended to protect the same resource.
For example, the value of reducing NOX emissions, in terms of reduced nitrification of surface
water bodies, might be estimated based on the estimated benefits of reducing the flow of
nutrients from non-point source run-off to surface water bodies (see also Benefits Transfer).

The concept and approach discussed above is different from  the restoration/replacement cost
approach used commonly in Natural Resource Damage Assessments (NRDA) (and incorporated
in damage assessment models developed by the Department  of the Interior (DOI) and the
National  Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA)).  The NRDA
restoration/replacement cost approach uses the  cost to restore, rehabilitate, or replace the
damaged natural resource, in addition to the value of lost uses during the period when the
resource is damaged, to determine how much the polluter should pay in compensation.  The
problem with using the cost of restoration or replacement as  a valuation technique is that there is
no direct link between the cost of the restoration activities and the value of the services provided
by a natural (ecological) resource that would be lost without restoration.  As a result, the
estimated cost to restore or replace the natural resource will likely bear little relationship to the
true social value or change in the value of the resource.

Avoidance Expenditures/Averting Behavior

Averting behavior  and defensive or avoidance expenditure analyses are more commonly applied
in efforts to estimate the benefits of actions that protect or improve human health. However,
such approaches also may be applicable in estimating the benefits of actions that improve the
state of an ecological resource.  This approach is also based on the concept of revealed
preference: by choosing to undertake the action, society demonstrates (or reveals) that it values
the resource or the improvement of the resource at least as much as the cost of the action
designed to protect or improve the resource. Some argue that this approach is inconsistent
because few environmental  actions and regulations are based solely on benefit-cost comparisons
(particularly at the national level). As a result,  the cost of a protective action may actually
exceed the benefits to society.  It is probably more likely, however, that the cost of those actions
already taken to protect an ecological resource will underestimate the benefits of a new action to
improve or protect the resource.

Using this approach to estimate the benefits of an action that protects an ecological resource, one
might look at the expenditures by society to prevent or reduce the negative impacts to the
resource as a measure of the value or benefits of that action.  For example, the cost of alternative
controls to reduce effluent emissions to a water body could be used to estimate the value or
benefits of reducing pollutant concentrations in the water body.

                                                                                 Page 119

-------
Bartik (1988) shows formally how changes in defensive expenditures by households to alleviate
the negative effects of pollution can be used to estimate the benefits of reducing pollutants.
Exhibit  18 presents some of the possible measures for estimating the benefits of reducing
pollutant levels using defensive expenditures:

                                       Exhibit 18
       Estimating the Benefits of Reducing Pollutants Using Defensive Expenditures
Pollutant
Air Pollution
Water Pollution
Hazardous Waste
Noise Pollution
Radon in well water
Radon in Soil Underneath House
Defensive Expenditure Measures
Clean or repaint exterior of house; install air
purifiers or new air conditioners; visit the
doctor more frequently; move away from
pollution source
New well; bottled water; water purifiers;
move away
Similar to both water and air pollution
depending upon medium by which hazardous
waste affects households
Storm windows; thicker walls; move away
Filter or aerate water; bottled water; increase
house air ventilation; move away
Ventilate crawlspace of house; seal
foundation of house; use thicker concrete in
basement; increase house air ventilation;
move away
Source: Bartik (1988).

Referenda

Referenda provide an institutional basis for asking individuals' preferences for certain goods and
services and may provide a basis for estimating the value of a particular change.  A typical
referendum might ask voters if they are willing to pay a specified amount to support a program
that increases the supply of a public good. The decision to vote "yes" is based on the individual
voter's assessment of whether the added benefit of the program exceeds the added cost of the
payment.  One of three conditions must exist to use an actual referendum to value a good or
service (Mitchell and Carson, 1989):

•      The same people must vote for different levels of the public good at a fixed tax level or
       for a fixed level of the good at different tax levels.  For example, a situation where a
       referendum fails and the supporters modify it for the next election;

       Different jurisdictions vote on the same level of a good; or
       Different jurisdictions vote on different levels of a good.
                                                                                 Page 120

-------
User Fees

User fee information, such as entrance fees or other fee receipts, can be used to infer the value
individuals place on the use of a specific site, such as a national park.  User fees indicate a lower
bound for the value that individuals place on the use of a specific site. At a minimum, it can be
assumed that each visitor values their visit (or use) of the ecological resource by at least as much
as they paid as an entrance fee or other charge to use the services provided by the ecological
resource. User fee data alone, however, is likely to significantly underestimate WTP, because it
misses values such as existence and option value and does not capture other "travel costs."

If one assumes that visitors react to increases in entrance fees in the same manner as to increases
in travel costs, entrance parameters can be used to trace a demand curve for the site, much in the
same way as under a travel cost study where the area under the demand curve is the measure of
the value of the ecological resource. In addition, it is possible to use entrance fees or other
charges assessed on users as a component of a broader travel cost or random utility model study.

Simulated Markets

Simulated market studies estimate what a person would pay for a good that is not sold on the
market by creating market conditions for that good. Under market conditions, the price that a
person will pay for a good or service is the value that the person places on that good or service.
Therefore, by mimicking market conditions, one should be able to estimate the value that  a
person places on public goods and services.

This technique can have advantages over other valuation methods,  such as contingent valuation
and travel cost. Like simulated market studies, these techniques attempt to attach value to public
goods; however, they do not simulate market conditions, and therefore certain biases exist that
affect their ability to estimate value.

There may  also be biases associated with simulated market studies, however, due to the
potentially  limited scope and artificial nature of the study. Additionally, conducting a simulated
market study could be potentially costly.  Simulated market studies may be most useful  in
limited contexts for interpreting the results and biases of contingent valuation, travel cost, and
other valuation techniques (Bishop and Heberlein, 1979).
                                                                                  Page 121

-------
Example Simulated Market Study (Bishop and Heberlein, 1979)

This study used simulated markets, contingent valuation, and travel cost to estimate the value of
goose hunting permits. Goose hunting permits were readily available — hunters wrote in and
requested permits for a specific season.  Each permit allowed the hunter to take one goose and no
fees were charged for the permits. Three samples of hunters were drawn from the total number
of hunters who were issued permits. For the simulated market approach, the first sample of
hunters received cash offers for their permits by mail; if the hunter accepted the offer, they were
to send the permit back, otherwise, the check.  The cash offers ranged between $1 and $200. A
second sample of hunters received contingent valuation questionnaires in the mail designed to
measure the value of the permits.  The third sample received travel cost questionnaires designed
to estimate a travel cost demand curve.

Responses to cash offers yielded a total consumer surplus for the permits of $800,000 total, or
$63 per permit.  The contingent valuation survey estimated that the average willingness-to-sell
was $101 per permit, while the average willingness-to-pay was $21 per permit. The travel cost
study estimated costs per permit of $11, $28, or $45  based on the assumptions regarding the
value of time (time value equals zero, 1/4 median income rate, and 1A median income rate,
respectively).

In theory, the simulated market study approximates the true value of the permit more closely
than a contingent valuation study would because real money was used, and people were asked to
make a choice similar to the market choices that are  made each day.
References and Further Reading

Adams, R.M. and T.D. Crocker.  1991.  "Materials Damages," in Braden, John B. and Charles D.
Kolstad, eds.  1991. Measuring the Demand for Environmental Quality. North-Holland,
Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers.

Bartik, TJ. 1988.  "Evaluating the Benefits of Non-marginal Reductions in Pollution Using
Information on Defensive Expenditures." Journal of Environmental Economics and
Management, 15: 111-127.

Bishop, R.C. and T. A. Heberlein.  1979. "Measuring Values of Extramarket Goods:  Are
Indirect Measures Biased?" American Journal of Agricultural Economics, December: 926-929.

Braden, J.B. and C.D. Kolstad, eds.  1991.  Measuring the Demand for Environmental Quality.
North-Holland, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers.

Freeman, A.M., III. 1993.  The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values: Theory
and Methods. Washington, D.C.:  Resources for the Future.
                                                                               Page 122

-------
Haniey, N. and C.L. Spash. 1993. Cost Benefit Analysis and the Environment.  Brookfield,
Vermont: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.

Just, R.E., D.L. Hueth, and A. Schmitz. 1982. Applied Welfare Economics and Public Policy.
Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall.

Loomis, J.B.  1993.  Integrated Public Lands Management:  Principles and Applications to
National Forests, Parks, Wildlife Refuges, and BLM Lands, Chapter 6, Applying Economic
Efficiency Analysis in Practice: Principles of Benefit-Cost Analysis. New York, New York:
Columbia University Press.
                                                                               Page 123

-------
6.3.3  Travel Cost Methodologies
                                                                          Revealed
                                                                         Preference
                                                                          Approach
The travel cost method was developed as a technique to value public recreation sites. This
technique incorporates the assumption that individuals visiting a recreational site pay an implicit
price for the site's services that includes the cost of travel to the site and the time spent visiting
the site. Travel cost models pay special attention to the value of time.

To illustrate the concept behind travel cost models, consider, for example, that on a particular
day a person chooses to go to work or to a park (or engage in some other activity). The person
must first decide whether or not to go to work and, if the person decides to go to the park, he or
she must decide how much time to spend there. The cost of the visit to the park includes the cost
of getting to the park, any entry fee that is paid, plus the foregone earnings, or opportunity cost,
one could have earned by going to work. If these costs and the number of trips made in one
season were assembled for a large population, the unit willingness-to-pay for a certain number of
visits could be estimated (Pearce and Turner,  1990).

In calculating the average willingness-to-pay  for a trip using the travel cost method, it is
important to note factors that require careful attention.  In determining the number of trips taken
by individuals, it is necessary to recognize that some visits may be multi-purpose trips and some
trips may be taken by holiday-makers while others may be taken by residents.  Furthermore, it
may be difficult to accurately calculate distance costs and the value of time associated with
visiting the site.  These factors may require special attention in order to accurately estimate the
value of the resources at the site (Hanley and  Spash, 1993).

To determine a demand curve for recreation at a specific site, it is necessary to understand that
trip costs are like prices.  Theory dictates that if prices are lower, people will consume a higher
quantity of the good, or,  in this case, if trip costs are lower,  people will take  more trips to the
site. By plotting trip cost against the number of trips to the recreation site from different areas, a
demand-curve for recreation days can be traced (Loomis, 1993).

Typically, travel cost models are used to estimate the demand curve for an individual, although
aggregate or market demand for a site might also be modeled. The consumer surplus for an
individual visitor is the area under the estimated demand curve but above the trip cost. Because
people come from different distances to use the site, consumer surplus is different for each user.
People living close to the site "buy" more trips and pay less per trip. Hence, these people receive
a much larger consumer  surplus than people living farther from  the site who "buy" fewer trips
and pay more per trip. In other words, people living close to the site are willing to pay more than
those living further away to have access to the site or to prevent deterioration of its
environmental quality. Total consumer surplus for all individuals is found by adding up all of
the trips from all locations and adding up each individual's consumer surplus. The average
consumer surplus per trip can be used as an estimate of the average willingness-to-pay for a trip
(Loomis, 1993).
                                                                                 Page 124

-------
Shifts in the demand curve due to an improvement in the quality of the site can be used to
estimate the change in the value of the site, or the benefit resulting from the improvement.2
Similarly, because environmental quality is expected to influence demand for a site, changes in
visitation rates for sites with different levels of environmental quality, holding travel costs
constant, can be used to estimate the benefit of changes in environmental quality (Pearce and
Turner, 1990).  However, the random utility model may be a more appropriate technique when
examining the choice between multiple sites.

       Advantages

X"     The travel cost method can provide benefit measures for changes in environmental
       quality from the observed behavior of visitors to recreation sites.

V     The method can be adapted to many environmental quality issues where changes in
       quality affect the desirability of a recreation site.

V     The method can be implemented using mail,  phone, interview surveys, or site registration
       data.  In some cases,  data are available from state and federal resource management
       agencies.

       Disadvantages

V     Travel cost studies may over- or under-estimate the value of a good or service if they use
       an inappropriate estimate for the market price of the time that people spend traveling to a
       recreation site.  Economists continue to disagree about whether the value of travel time
       should be based on the person's wage rate, some fraction of their wage rate, or valued at
       zero.

X"     The method can provide benefits information only on changes in environmental quality
       that have a direct effect on the site preferences of recreationists.  Quality  characteristics
       that users are indifferent to or unaware of cannot be evaluated.

V     Exclusion of alternative recreation sites and their characteristics (environmental quality
       and other site features) from the travel cost model may bias the benefit estimates.

X"     Excludes non-use values.

V     Environmental quality and other site characteristics may be difficult to describe in
       quantitative terms.

Data Requirements
       2 Because the travel cost method does not provide for estimation of the theoretically correct
measure of WTP for a site or for changes in the environmental quality at a site, such estimates should be
used cautiously.  Furthermore, because of this potential limitation, one might consider the appropriateness
of utilizing a method of exact welfare measurement, where the functional form for the travel cost demand
curve is derived from an explicit specification of the individual's utility function (Freeman, 1993).

                                                                                  Page 125

-------
Travel cost models typically have the following data needs: (1) the county of residence or zip
code for users of the recreation site, population size, and summary measures for features of the
population in each origin zone; (2) round-trip mileage to the site and to substitute sites; (3) mode
of transportation; (4) vehicle operating costs per mile and implicit time cost of travel; and (5)
data on on-site characteristics, such as size, number, location, and type of facilities. Typically,
this information is collected through surveys using phone, on-site, or mail surveys, or by
acquiring site registration data.
Example Travel Cost Study (Bockstael et al, 1989)

A travel cost model was used to estimate the value of improved water quality to Maryland beach
users on the western shore of the Chesapeake Bay. Water quality was measured as the product
of the concentrations of nitrogen and phosphorous in the water at the monitoring site nearest to
the beach in question.  Data for the model was obtained from a survey of 484 people at 11 public
beaches in the study area.

The model was used to calculate the willingness to pay for a 20 percent improvement in water
quality - that is, a 20 percent reduction on total nitrogen and phosphorus.  The average annual
aggregate benefits to beach users of water quality improvement were estimated to be $35 million
(1984 dollars). The long-run benefits to beach users of water quality improvements may be
higher than the estimates reported, however, for several reasons. First, as people learn that the
Bay has become cleaner, they will adjust their preferences toward beach recreation. People who
do not currently use the Bay beaches will be especially likely to make this change. Additionally,
the population and income of the area have grown and are likely to continue growing, increasing
the demand for and value of the water quality improvements. Finally, the estimates given ignore
households outside the Baltimore-Washington Statistical Metropolitan Sampling Area.
References and Further Reading

Bishop, R.C. and T.A. Heberlein. 1979. "Measuring Values of Extramarket Goods: Are
Indirect Measures Biased?"  American Journal of Agricultural Economics., December:  926-929.

Bockstael, N.E., K.E. McConnell, and I.E. Strand.  1989. "Measuring the Benefits of
Improvements in Water Quality: The Chesapeake Bay." Marine Resource Economics 6(1): 1-
18.

Bockstael, N.E., K.E. McConnell, and I.E. Strand.  1991. "Recreation." in Braden, J.B. and C.D.
Kolstad, eds.  1991. Measuring the Demand for Environmental Quality.  North-Holland,
Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers.

Fletcher, J., W. Adamowicz, and T. Graham-Tomasi.  1990.  "The Travel Cost Model of
Recreation Demand." Leisure Sciences 12: 119-147.
                                                                                Page 126

-------
Freeman, A.M., III.  1993. The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values:  Theory
and Methods. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future.

Haniey, N. and C. Spash. 1993. Cost Benefit Analysis and the Environment. Brookfield,
Vermont: Edward Elgar Publishing.

Loomis, J.B.  1993. Integrated Public Lands Management: Principles and Applications to
National Forests, Parks, Wildlife Refuges, and BLM Lands, Chapter 6, Applying Economic
Efficiency Analysis in Practice:  Principles of Benefit-Cost Analysis. New York: Columbia
University Press.

McConnell K. and I. Strand.  1981.  "Measuring the Cost of Time in Recreation Demand
Analysis." American Journal of Agricultural Economics:  153-156.

Pearce, D.W. and R.K. Turner.  1990. Economics of Natural Re sources and the Environment.
Maryland: The Johns Hopkins University Press.

Willis, K. and G. Garrod. 1991. "An Individual Travel Cost Method of Evaluating Forest
Recreation." Journal of'AgriculturalEconomics 42(1): 33-42.
                                                                              Page 127

-------
6.3.4  Random Utility Model
                                                                         Revealed
                                                                         Preference
                                                                         Approach
The random utility model is a popular method to estimate consumers' recreational demand. The
random utility model is also known as a "discrete choice model" because it is used to study
people's choices between one or more alternatives. The term "random" refers to the fact that the
model cannot directly observe people's decision processes.  The economist observes the final
decision but must assume the decision process is logical, with people choosing the alternative
providing the greatest possible level of satisfaction.  The lack of direct observation is what
makes the process "random" to an economist.

With respect to valuing changes to ecological resources, the use of random utility models
focuses on the choices individuals make among substitute sites for any given recreational trip
rather than the number of trips a recreationist takes to a given site in a season, as with the travel
cost model. The random utility model is especially suitable when the selection of alternatives or
substitutes differ in terms of their quality or other characteristics.  The random utility model is
particularly appropriate when there are many substitutes available  and when the change being
valued is a change in a specific quality characteristic  of one or more sites, such as catch rates or
water quality. The random utility  model can also be used to value the benefits of introducing a
new site (U.S. EPA, 1995).

The characteristics of the alternative sites that are used in the estimation of the model are
instrumental in explaining how people allocate their trips across sites.  Sometimes information
on the characteristics of the individuals making the choices are also used in estimating a random
utility model.

       Advantages

X"     The random utility model can provide benefit measures for changes in environmental
       quality from the observed behavior of visitors to recreation sites.

X"     The method can be adapted to many environmental quality issues where changes in
       quality affect  the desirability of a recreation site.

V     This technique is preferred over the travel cost model for handling the issues of substitute
       sites and environmental quality considerations.

       Disadvantages

V     An inappropriate estimate for the value of time that people spend traveling to a site can
       adversely affect the estimated value of the good or service.

X"     The method can provide benefits information only on changes in environmental quality
       that have a direct effect on the site preferences of recreationists. Quality characteristics
       that users are  indifferent to or unaware of cannot be evaluated.

X"     Model specification, as with all techniques and estimation procedures, can have a
       significant impact on benefit estimates.

                                                                                 Page 128

-------
V     This technique requires a significant amount of data.

X"     Benefit estimates may be biased if: (1) known substitute sites are not included in the
       model or (2) additional substitute sites are included in the model that are unknown to the
       individuals surveyed.

V     Excludes non-use values.

Data Requirements

The random utility model has data needs similar to those of the travel cost model, including the
cost of travel to the site or information to estimate the cost (i.e.,  distance traveled, any fees paid,
plus the value of the individual's time) and characteristics of the chosen site and alternative sites.
In addition, the researcher needs to know what alternative sites are considered by recreationists
and may want to collect information on the characteristics of the individuals (e.g., education,
income, other socio-demographic information). Additionally, accurate measurement of the
characteristics of the alternative sites is necessary.
Example Random Utility Study (Englin et al, 1991)

This study uses both the random utility model and the travel cost method to estimate the
damages to recreational trout fishing in the Upper Northeast due to acidic deposition.  Data were
collected on freshwater recreational trips made during the summer of 1989 by 5,724 randomly
selected individuals in four Northeastern states: Maine, New Hampshire, New York, and
Vermont. Changes in acidic deposition were expected to impact fish populations by changing
acidic stress levels, thereby changing catch rates of various species. An angler's well-being
should change when a change in the catch rate causes him or her to enjoy a site less (more) or
results in a decision to change sites and travel farther (closer).  The two models are based on the
premise that the cost of travel to a site can be used to represent the price of a recreational fishing
site.

The random utility model provides estimates of changes in the value per choice occasion based
on the relevant changes in the quality characteristics of the sites available to anglers. The model
estimates that damages from acidic deposition are approximately $0.12 per trip. The travel cost
model estimates the willingness to pay for a marginal increase in each attribute. With this
technique, the willingness to pay for no damages from acidification was found to be $0.02 per
trip.
                                                                                 Page 129

-------
References and Further Reading

Bockstael, N.E., K.E. McConnell, and I. Strand. 1989. "A Random Utility Model for
Sportfishing:  Some Preliminary Results for Florida."  Marine Resource Economics 6(1989):
245-260.

Englin, I.E., T.A. Cameron, R.E. Mendelsohn, G.A. Parsons, and S.A. Shankle.  1991.
Valuation of Damages to Recreational Trout Fishing in the Upper Northeast due to Acidic
Deposition. Richland, Washington:  Pacific Northwest Laboratory. Prepared for National Acidic
Precipitation Assessment Program.

Hanemann, W.M.  1984 "Welfare Evaluations in Contingent Valuation Experiments with
Discrete Responses." American Journal of Agricultural Economics, August, 66: 332-341.

Kaoru, Y., V. K. Smith, and J.L. Liu.  1995 "Using Random Utility Models to Estimate the
Recreational Value of Estuarine Resources." American Journal of Agricultural Economics.,
February, 77: 141-151.

Smith, V.K. 1989 "Taking Stock of Progress with Travel Cost Recreation Demand Methods:
Theory and Implementation." Marine Resource Economics 6: 279-310.

U.S. EPA, Oceans and Coastal Protection Division.  1995. Assessing the Economic Value of
Estuary Resources and Re source Services in Comprehensive Conservation and Management
Plan (CCMP) Planning and Implementation, A National Estuary Program Environmental
Valuation Handbook. Washington, D.C.
                                                                              Page 130

-------
6.3.5  Hedonic Price and Hedonic Wage Methodologies
                         Revealed
                        Preference
                         Approach
Hedonic methods typically use residential housing prices or labor wage rates, as well as other
data, to measure the value of specific characteristics of a home, property, or job. These analyses
identify the indirect linkage between environmental quality and the market price of a good or
service, such as a residential property or employment opportunity, and use this linkage to
estimate the implicit price, or benefit, of improvements in environmental quality. Under
appropriate conditions, this implicit price can be interpreted as an individual's willingness-to-pay
for environmental quality.  In other situations, however, it is very difficult, if not impossible, to
measure the welfare effects of a change to a specific characteristic, such as environmental
quality. Nonetheless, the hedonic approach can still be useful for estimating a demand function
for an environmental quality characteristic,  such as the demand for proximity to a water body or
distance from a hazardous waste facility.

Hedonic Price

The hedonic price, or property valuation, technique uses the assumption that the price of a house
is a function of the characteristics of the home such as the quality of the surrounding
neighborhood, the location of the home relative to business centers, and environmental
characteristics including local air and water quality. The hedonic property model focuses on
how changes in environmental quality affect property values by studying data from housing
markets in different areas.  Studying the relationships between changes in property values and
differences in environmental quality can sometimes be used to determine an individual's
willingness-to-pay for improved environmental  quality (Palmquist, 1991).  The graph below
illustrates the relationship between environmental quality and property values that might be
uncovered by the hedonic property model.  It shows that property values rise at a declining rate
as the pollution level decreases or environmental quality improves. Other shapes of the hedonic
function may be possible.

                                        Figure 1
                     Graphic Illustration of a Hedonic Price Equation
            for an Environmental Quality Attribute (Pearce and Turner, 1990)
                          Property
                          Price, PP'
                          Pollution Level
Environmental Quality, E
                                                                                 Page 131

-------
When a change in environmental quality affects a large population, however, the hedonic
property model alone may not be adequate to measure the change in welfare, or willingness-to-
pay, and a more complicated analysis is required. In this case, some knowledge of the
consumers' preferences and a knowledge or a forecast of the change in the hedonic price
equation (represented by PP' in Figure 1) is necessary (Palmquist, 1991). A full discussion of
this issue is beyond the scope of this document.

In valuing changes in environmental quality, the hedonic approach attempts to do two things:

       Identify how much of a property price differential is due to a particular environmental
       difference between properties; and

•      Infer how much people are willing to pay for an improvement in the environmental
       quality they experience (Pearce and Turner, 1990).

For example, all  other things being equal, one would expect prices of houses in neighborhoods
with clean air to be higher than prices for houses in neighborhoods with polluted air.  By
comparing the market values of similar houses in areas with different levels of air quality, one
may be able to determine that part of the difference in the price of housing in the two areas can
serve as a measure of the value of clean air  (Tietenberg, 1992).
Example Hedonic Pricing Study (Palmquist et a/., 1997)

Palmquist, Roka, and Vukina used the hedonic pricing model to analyze the effects of hog
operations on nearby houses. The authors examined the amount of hog manure located at
varying distances from residential properties. Their purpose was to determine whether the
presence of hogs influenced property values.

Results from the hedonic model show that the presence of hog operations had a statistically
significant negative effect on nearby property values. Changes in house values decreased as
much as approximately $5,000  for a home located within l/2 mile of a projected hog operation
and as little as $1 for homes located 2 miles from the projected site in an area with higher
concentrations of hog operations. The results indicated that the strongest negative impacts
occurred closest to the hog operation and that effects on property value decreased as distance to
the operations increased. Furthermore, in areas of high concentrations of hog operations, growth
of hog operations experienced smaller negative effects than those areas with low concentrations
of hog operations.
                                                                                 Page 132

-------
Example Hedonic Pricing Study (Edwards and Anderson, 1984)

Edwards and Anderson performed a hedonic price analysis that related the value of a house and
its lot to characteristics of the house such as square footage, number of bathrooms, age, size of
lot, and the following coastal zone characteristics: distance to a salt pond or ocean, frontage on a
salt pond or ocean, and the presence of a view of the pond or ocean from the property.  Their
purpose was to determine the lost economic value to property owners associated with a zoning
restriction in Narragansett Bay, Rhode Island.

The results of the study suggest that the saltwater view and proximity to a salt pond are valued
attributes of houses in the region. Using the estimated hedonic price equation, an approximate
value of a water view was $5,790. It was further estimated that a land use policy restricting
residential zoning in the salt pond region to protect groundwater supplies and water quality
would result in lost opportunities for water view and water frontage locations valued at
approximately $407,200.
Hedonic Wage

The hedonic wage technique is based on the presumption that, other things being equal, workers
will prefer jobs with more pleasant working conditions.  As the number of people seeking out the
more pleasant jobs increases, the wages offered for such jobs will fall.  Conversely, employers
will have to raise the wage they offer for jobs with less pleasant working conditions to attract
employees to these jobs.  Therefore,  at an equilibrium, the monetary value of better working
conditions will be reflected in the difference in wages between two jobs with different working
conditions (Freeman, 1993).

Hedonic models are generally used to perform two types of valuations. The first, and more
common, usage concerns the value of reducing the risk of death, injury or illness. In labor
markets, workers that face higher levels of environmental or other job-related risk are
compensated for that risk with higher than average wages.  By estimating the dollar amount by
which wages are increased to compensate workers for the greater risk, one can value the benefits
that would be conferred by a reduction in the risk of death, injury, or illness (Tietenberg, 1992;
Viscusi, 1993). Hedonic wage studies used to value the risk of illness or mortality may produce
inaccurate results, however, if they do not account for the possible self-select!on of less risk
averse individuals into riskier jobs.

Hedonic wage techniques can also be used, however, to value the environmental, social, and
cultural amenities that vary across regions. This usage assumes that those cities and regions that
are more desirable places to live and work in will attract workers from less desirable regions. As
a result, employers in more desirable locations will pay lower wages, on average, than employers
in less desirable locations for a worker with the  same training and experience. Hedonic wage
models try to measure the differences in wages between regions, or the "compensating wage
differential,"  to estimate the monetary value of differences in amenities (Freeman, 1993).
                                                                                 Page 133

-------
Example Hedonic Wage Study (Bayless, 1982)

Bayless used a hedonic wage analysis to relate the wages paid to academic professors and the air
quality of the surrounding area. Bayless estimated a hedonic wage equation for salary of
professors that incorporated pollution measures, as well as factors of productivity and locational
characteristics.  Bayless then used the hedonic wage equation to estimate a demand function for
clean air, which was then used to estimate the willingness-to-pay for better air quality.

This analysis found that the professors would be willing to pay approximately $100 to $400 per
year in salary to move from areas of low air quality to high air quality.  Willingness-to-pay
values increased as the disparity in air quality between locations increased.
       Advantages

       The hedonic techniques use market data on property sales prices and labor wages, these
       data are usually available through several sources and can be related to other secondary
       data sources to obtain descriptive variables for the analysis.

       The technique is versatile and can be adapted to consider several possible interactions
       between market goods and environmental quality.

       The hedonic method provides estimates of individuals' preferences for changes in
       environmental quality, which, under special conditions, can be interpreted as benefit
       measures.

       Disadvantages

       The assumptions necessary to interpret the results of the hedonic technique as benefit
       measures are restrictive and, in many real world settings, implausible.  Market
       equilibrium conditions require full knowledge of environmental effects that may be
       imperceptible to the physical senses. For example, if there are subtle long-term changes
       in water quality associated with some housing sites but people are unaware of the causal
       link of the effects to the housing site, their willingness-to-pay to avoid the effects will not
       be reflected in housing  price differences.

       Benefit  estimates from  a single product class will likely only capture a part of an
       individual's preferences for environmental quality. Property value models, for instance,
       are based on the consequences of individuals' choices of residence and therefore do not
       capture  willingness-to-pay for improvements in environmental amenities at other points
       in the area, such as parks and recreational areas.

       The estimating equations used for the hedonic technique may be statistically sensitive to
       model specification and estimation decisions.  Appropriate tests for unbiasedness in
       housing and wage studies are still being developed.
                                                                                  Page 134

-------
V    Complete data on property or job characteristics may be difficult and expensive to gather,
       especially environment related characteristics. The omission of relevant characteristics
       and/or interactive environmental effects may reduce the validity of benefit estimates.

X"    It may be difficult to isolate the specific amenity or environmental characteristic that is of
       interest.

V    Excludes non-use values.

Data Requirements

Data needs include sales or income, prices, wage data, characteristics of houses sold or jobs, and
environmental amenity characteristics for each area of interest. These data can be collected from
organizations such as multiple listing agencies, local tax assessors, and federal government
agencies.  Environmental quality data may be available from state, regional, or federal agencies
and databases. Data collection, therefore, can often be time-consuming because of the effort
required to gather data from a range of sources.  The data sets can be gathered from markets that
are separated either spatially or temporally or from a single market, although data from multiple
markets tend to capture variation in price schedules, which may yield more accurate results.
Additionally, while the data may be available, another problem may be the question of how
individuals perceive their environment and whether individuals are aware of the quality of their
environment. Most hedonic analysis use objective measures of environmental quality.
However, some researchers have used subjective indicators, such as visibility, to determine
environmental quality (Palmquist, 1991).

References and Further Reading

Bartik, TJ.  1988.  "Measuring the Benefits of Amenity Improvements in Hedonic Price
Models." Land Economics 64(2):  172-183.

Bayless, M. 1982. "Measuring the Benefits of Air Quality Improvements: A Hedonic Salary
Approach." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 9(2): 81-99.

Edwards, S.F. and G.D. Anderson. 1984. "Land Use Conflicts in Coastal Zone:  An Approach
for the Analysis of the Opportunity Costs of Protecting Coastal Resources." Journal of the
Northeastern Agricultural Economics Council 13(1): 78-81.

Freeman, A. M., III.  1993.  The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values: Theory
and Methods. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future.

Palmquist, R.  1991. "Hedonic Methods." in Braden, John B.  and Charles D. Kolstad, eds.
Measuring the Demand for Environmental Quality. North-Holland, Amsterdam: Elsevier
Science Publishers.

Palmquist, R.B., F. Roka, and T. Vukina.  1997.  "Hog Operations, Environmental Effects, and
Residential Property Values." Land Economics  73(1):  114-124.
                                                                                Page 135

-------
Pearce, D.W. and R.K. Turner. 1990. Economics of Natural Resources and the Environment.
Maryland: The Johns Hopkins University Press.

Tietenberg, T.  1992. Environmental and Natural Resource Economics. HarperCollins
Publisher.

Viscusi, W. K. 1993. "The Value of Risks to Life and Health." Journal of Economic
Literature.  XXXI(4): 1912-1946.
                                                                              Page 136

-------
6.3.6  Contingent Valuation
                                                                           Stated
                                                                         Preference
                                                                         Approach
Contingent valuation studies rely on surveys to ascertain respondent preferences for
environmental goods and services by determining how much someone is willing to pay for
changes in the quantity or quality of the good or service. These methods do not depend on
market data; instead they establish a hypothetical market that gives survey respondents the
opportunity to purchase the good or service. The dollar value that individual respondents are
willing to pay for the good or service, when aggregated, can provide a means to value the good
or service "sold" in the hypothetical market (Mitchell and Carson, 1989; Bateman and  Willis,
1998; Cummings et al, 1986).  Because this method does not rely on market data, it can be
applied to a variety of environmental quality issues for which market-based information is not
available, including the elicitation of non-use values.

Contingent valuation is a technique whereby people are asked what they are willing to pay for a
benefit or what they are willing to receive by way of compensation to tolerate the loss  of a good
or service. The individual responses are aggregated to derive a demand curve for the good or
service.

A contingent valuation study is conducted either by written survey, interview, or some
combination, and it generally consists of four parts:

•       Background information on the situation and possible changes to be made.

•       A detailed description of the good(s) or change to the good(s) being valued and the
       hypothetical method of payment.

       Questions to elicit the respondents' willingness-to-pay for the good(s) or the change
       being valued.

•       Questions to collect socio-demographic (e.g., age, income); to validate the WTP response
       (e.g., what are their preferences relevant to the good(s) being valued, why did they give
       that dollar value); and to model their use of the good(s)  (e.g., how frequently they visit
       the site).

The aim of contingent valuation is to elicit valuations, or "bids," that are close to those that
would be revealed if an actual market existed.  The questioner,  questionnaire, and respondent
therefore, must represent as real a market as possible. For example, the respondent should be
familiar with the good in question, such as improved scenic visibility, and with the hypothetical
means of payment, such as a local tax or entry charge.

Several individuals and groups have identified specific criteria for conducting reliable  contingent
valuation studies (Bjornstad and Kahn, 1996; Arrow et al, 1993; and Carson etal., 1996).
Generally, these criteria include (at a minimum):

•       Interview a large sample of the affected population;

•       Achieve a high response rate;

                                                                                 Page 137

-------
•      Conduct in-person interviews when feasible;

•      Pre-test the questionnaire for interview effects and other potential biases;

•      Provide an accurate description of the event, program, or policy choice and the
       commodity to be valued; and

       Remind interviewees of their budget constraints and the availability of comparable goods
       and services.

While these guidelines are useful in assessing the reliability of a  contingent valuation study, less
restrictive and less costly approaches may be appropriate for informing policy decisions.  In
addition, some studies have found some of the above criteria (e.g., budget reminders) to have no
effect on value estimates (Loomis, etal., 1994).

       Advantages

X"     The contingent valuation method can be used to estimate the benefits of a variety of
       environmental effects for which market or secondary data are not available.

X"     Comparisons of benefit measures from well-done contingent valuation studies with
       benefit estimates from other direct and indirect market techniques suggest that
       respondents can generally provide reasonable and consistent values for changes in
       environmental quality.

V     Contingent valuation methods are the only methods available for estimating non-use
       values (e.g., existence values).

X"     The willingness-to-pay estimates from contingent valuation include both the use and
       nonuse value of the good or service.

V     Survey-based contingent valuation methods can capture respondents' attitudinal and
       behavioral information that are not available in other non-survey based valuation
       techniques.

X"     Useful for estimating non-use values.

       Disadvantages

V     The contingent valuation method is based on hypothetical situations in which it is
       difficult to verify whether expressed preferences are consistent with actual or planned
       behavior.  Attempts to minimize the hypothetical nature of the process may only be partly
       successful.

X"     Survey participants learn about their preferences for environmental quality during the
       valuation exercise. Survey design features may have a significant effect on this learning
       process and lead to responses that may not represent participants' true preferences.

                                                                                  Page 138

-------
       Conditional choice settings that are not at least partly familiar to the respondent may lead
       to uncertain responses.

       Survey research is costly and time-consuming. National benefit estimates require
       properly designed sampling and enumeration procedures. Respondent refusals to
       consider environmental tradeoffs, as discussed in the choice exercises can raise questions
       regarding the validity of the benefit estimates.

       Participants may answer strategically (high or low). Participants may provide
       unrealistically high answers if they believe that they will not have to pay for the good or
       service, but expect that their answer may influence the resulting supply of the good. This
       could lead to an overestimate of the actual willingness-to-pay.  On the other hand, if
       participants believe that they might have to pay for the good or service based on the
       results of the survey, they might answer in such a way to keep the price low, and thereby
       cause surveyors to underestimate the value of the good or service.

       Contingent valuation studies do not always find that WTP increases when the quality or
       quantity of a good or service increases.
Example Contingent Valuation Study (Whittington et a/., 1994)

A contingent valuation survey was conducted of randomly selected households in the Greater
Houston-Galveston Area to assess residents' willingness-to-pay for improvements in Galveston
Bay's environmental quality and ecological health. In total, 234 interviews were completed in a
mail/in-person follow-up survey, and 393 interviews in a mail-only survey. The analysis of
responses showed that high-income respondents were more likely to vote for the management
plan at a given price than low-income respondents; that users of the Bay were more likely to
support the plan than passive users; and that people in general were less likely to vote for the
management plan as the price of the plan presented as a monthly surcharge on their water bill
increased.

Based on the results of the mail-only contingent valuation survey, after adjusting results to
account for differences between the socioeconomic profiles of respondents and the population of
the study area, the authors  estimated that the average household in the Greater Houston-
Galveston Area is willing to pay approximately $7 per month, or about $80 per year, over five
years for the management plan described in the questionnaire.
Elicitation Methods

There are several elicitation methods that are used in contingent valuation studies to determine
an individual's willingness-to-pay. These methods represent different approaches for asking the
respondent about their willingness-to-pay.
                                                                                 Page 139

-------
The four methods discussed here include:

•      Direct, open-ended questioning
•      Payment card
•      Referendum/dichotomous choice
•      Iterative bidding games

Each of these approaches is described below.

Direct Open-Ended Questioning

When using the direct open-ended questioning method, respondents are asked directly,

       "How much would you be willing to pay for the change in the good or service
       described?"

Although the most obvious approach, it is also one of the most problematic methods.

       Advantages

X"     Does not require pre-testing to determine an appropriate range for values as do the
       payment card and referendum voting methods.

X"     Appears to provide conservative estimates of WTP.

       Disadvantages

X"     Difficult for people to respond to an open-ended question because they are usually not
       accustomed to valuing environmental goods and services and typically do not face this
       type of question in a market situation.

V     May result in a high non-response rate and high number of extreme values (e.g., zeros
       and very large values).

Payment Card

The payment card method incorporates properties similar to the direct questioning approach but
increases the response rates of willingness-to-pay questions. The payment card method asks the
respondent to choose a willingness-to-pay amount from a card with a range of possible
willingness-to-pay amounts usually starting from $0. The card sometimes indicates the average
amount households of the same income range are willing to pay for other public goods (Mitchell
and Carson, 1989).  The payment card method, particularly with an average amount from other
households, is no longer used in contingent valuation studies, but is described here for reference
in reviewing older studies.
                                                                               Page 140

-------
Under this approach the respondent is asked:

       "What amount on this card or any amount in between is the most that you would be
       willing to pay for the level of good being proposed?

       Advantages

X"     Provides more of a context for the respondent to provide a value.

X"     Easier for respondent to select a value than to respond to an open-ended question.

       Disadvantages

X"     Susceptible to biases associated with the ranges shown on card and the benchmark values
       provided by other households in the same income range.

Referendum Voting/Dichotomous Choice

Referendum voting/dichotomous choice is a technique where an individual is offered a fixed
quantity of a good at a fixed price on a take-it-or-leave-it or yes-no basis.  This is currently the
favored approach for eliciting willingness-to-pay (WTP) estimates from survey respondents.
Referendum voting as an elicitation method for contingent valuation differs from the use of
actual referendum data described under Market-Based Valuation Approaches, in that a
contingent valuation study referendum vote is a hypothetical scenario. While often referred to
interchangeably, referendum style format and dichotomous choice can be distinct approaches. A
survey could use a  referendum scenario with more than two voting options (see example from
contingent referendum section) and dichotomous choice could be used without a referendum
scenario. Observing and analyzing the choices that individuals make through these techniques
reveals the value of the good as it relates to the offered price (Freeman, 1993). For example, if
someone accepts an offer to pay $10 a year in additional property taxes to preserve a wilderness
area, it can be assumed that the person values the area by at least $10.  If the resource was valued
at less than $10, the person would not have accepted the $10 fee in a vote. However, the person
may value the resource at more than $10 a year, and unless iterative voting is permitted, it would
be impossible to determine the maximum that the voter is willing to pay.  For this reason,
referendum or dichotomous choice questions are often presented with one or two follow-up
questions that present the respondent with a second choice scenario. This two-stage, or double-
bounded, approach increases the statistical efficiency of the valuation estimate and reduces the
necessary sample size.
                                                                                Page 141

-------
       Advantages

       Voting is a familiar social context, therefore respondents are likely to feel comfortable
       answering this type of question.

       A vote provides a simple decision problem (either "yes" or "no").

       If the referendum questions are asked without an implied value judgment, there should be
       no starting point bias affecting the answers (Freeman, 1993).

       Recent analysis has found the referendum question format to be strategic compatible (i.e.,
       respondents are not expected to provide unrealistically high or low values for strategic
       purposes of supporting or suppressing the proposed (action).

       Disadvantages

       Referendum voting requires more data and a larger sample size than direct questioning.

       The outcome of referendum voting may be dependent on the distribution of offered bids,
       particularly the highest offered bid, because some respondents may be yea-saying or
       agreeing to pay any bid, no matter how high.

       Outcomes of referendum voting may be dependent on the statistical methods used to
       analyze the responses.  (See Haab and McConnell, 1997.)
Example Contingent Valuation Study (Carson etal., 1996)

A contingent valuation study using the referendum voting elicitation method was conducted by
the National Opinion Research Center in 1993 of 1,182 residents in 12 U.S. cities to estimate the
willingness-to-pay of individuals for a plan to provide two Coast Guard ships to escort oil
tankers through the Prince William Sound to prevent future accidents and injuries due to oil
spills. Willingness-to-pay was measured in terms of a one-time addition to Federal income
taxes. During personal interviews, respondents were asked if they would be willing to pay  a $10,
$30, $60, or $120 one-time payment (each respondent was randomly assigned a dollar value).
Based on the number of individuals willing to pay each dollar amount, the expected willingness-
to-pay per individual was estimate to range from $50.61 to $52.81.
                                                                                Page 142

-------
Iterative Bidding Games

Generally bidding games are conducted through personal interviews where the interviewer
iteratively questions the respondent.  Although this approach is generally no longer used because
of bias issues, it is described here for reference in reviewing older studies.

Questions are structured to lead to a  "yes" or "no" response. For example, to estimate the value
of environmental improvements, the interviewer might ask,

       "Would you continue to use this area if the cost to you was to increase by X
       dollars?" or

       "Would you be willing to pay an increase in your monthly electric bill of X dollars
       for Y reduction in air pollution?"

The amount is varied with the same individual and the highest "yes" answer is recorded.

       Advantages

X"     Able to get maximum willingness-to-pay  from each individual surveyed.

X"     May not require as large a sample as other approaches.

       Disadvantages

V     The outcomes of bidding games have been found to be highly dependent on the starting
       point, or first offered bid.

X"     It can be difficult to develop a credible bidding game; the situation presented to survey
       respondents must be realistic and  credible to the participants. Because of these
       difficulties, few recent contingent valuation surveys use bidding games to elicit values.

Data Requirements

The primary data for a contingent valuation analysis are acquired from a clearly defined and
pretested survey of people who are representative of an affected population.  A representative
sample of the affected must be identified  to allow extrapolation to the full affected population.
Some additional research may also be required to determine the extent of the affected population
or market for the good or service  affected by the proposed action.

The survey should generate data on respondents' willingness-to-pay for (or willingness-to-
accept) a program or plan that will affect their well-being, as well as socio-demographic
information and other data required to test for potential biases.  A critical component of the data
collection or survey implementation is the transfer of information to respondents about the
resource, resource service, or action they  are being asked to value. Photographs, verbal
descriptions, video, and other multimedia techniques  are commonly used to convey this
information. In conducting a contingent valuation survey, the quality of the results depends in

                                                                                 Page 143

-------
large part on the amount of information that is known beforehand about the way people think
about the good or service in question.

References and Further Reading

Alberini, A.  1995. "Optimal Designs for Discrete Choice Contingent Valuation Surveys:
Single-Bounded, Double-Bounded, and Bivariate Models." Journal of Environmental
Economics and Management, 28(3): 287-306.

Arrow, K., R. Solow, P.R. Portney, E.E. Learner, R. Radner, and H. Schuman. 1993. "Report of
the NOAA Panel on Contingent Valuation." Federal Register, January, Vol. 58(10): 4601-4614.

Bateman, IJ. and K.G. Willis, Eds. 1998. Valuing Environmental Preferences: Theory and
Practice of the Contingent Valuation Method in the  U.S., E.U., and Developing Countries.
Oxford University Press,  Oxford.

Bishop, R.C. and T. A. Heberlein.  1979. "Measuring Values of Extramarket Goods: Are
Indirect Measures Biased?" American Journal of Agricultural Economics, December: 926-929.

Bjornstad, DJ. and J.R. Kahn, eds. 1996. The Contingent Valuation of Environmental
Resources: Methodological Issues and Research Needs. Brookfield, Vermont: Edgar Elgar
Publishing Ltd.

Carson, R.T. et al.  1996.  "Was the NOAA Panel Correct About Contingent Valuation? "
Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future.

Cooper, J.C. and J. Loomis.  1992. "Sensitivity of Willingness to Pay to Bid Design in
Dichotomous Choice Contingent Valuation." Land Economics., 68(2): 211-224.

Cooper, J.C. 1993.  "Optimal Bid Selection for Dichotomous Choice Contingent Valuation."
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 24(1): 25-40.

Cummings, R.C., D. S. Brookshire, and W.D. Schulze, Eds.  Valuing Environmental Goods: An
Assessment of the Contingent Valuation Method. Rowan and Allanheld Publishers, Totowa, NJ.

Freeman, A.M., III. 1993. The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values: Theory
and Methods. Washington, D.C.:  Resources for the Future.

Haab, T. C., and K. E. McConnell. 1997. "Referendum Models and Negative Willingness to
Pay: Alternative Solutions."  Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 32(2):
251-270.

Kannimen, B.J. 1993. "Design of Sequential Experiments for Contingent Valuation Studies."
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 25(1): sl-sll.
                                                                              Page 144

-------
Loomis, J., A. Gonzales-Caban, and R. Gregory. 1994. "Do Reminders of Substitutes and
Budget Constraints Influence Contingent Valuation Estimates?" Land Economics.  70(4): 499-506.

Mitchell, R.C. and R.T. Carson.  1984. An Experiment in Determining Willingness to Pay for
National Water Quality Improvements. Washington D.C.:  Resources for the Future.

Mitchell, R.C. and R.T. Carson.  1986. The Use of Contingent Valuation Data for Benefit/Cost
Analysis in Water Pollution Control.  Washington D.C.:  Resources for the Future.

Mitchell, R.C. and R.T. Carson.  1989. Using Surveys to Value Public Goods: The Contingent
Valuation Method.  Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future.

Randall, A., B. Ives, and C. Eastman. 1974. "Bidding Games for Valuation of Aesthetic
Environmental Improvements." Journal of Environmental Economics 1: 132-149.

Whittington, D., et al.  1994.  The Economic Value of Improving the Environmental Quality of
Galveston Bay.  Galveston National Estuary Program. Publication GBNEP-3B.
                                                                               Page 145

-------
6.3.7  Combining Contingent Valuation with Other
	Approaches: Contingent Activity	
   Stated
Preference
Approach
In a contingent activity or contingent behavior study individuals are asked how they would
change their behavior in response to a change in an environmental amenity.  For example, one
could use a contingent activity to estimate how a demand function for visits to a recreational site
would shift with a change in one of the site's environmental attributes. Assuming that one has
already estimated the demand for visits to a site under current conditions, the analyst asks
visitors how their visitation behavior would change as a result of a change in an environmental
attribute of the site (e.g., change in water quality).  This information can then be used to estimate
a shift in the demand curve for visits to the site (Freeman,  1993).

In essence, a contingent activity approach combines the technique of contingent valuation with
other valuation approaches used to model demand for a particular good or service to extend the
application of these models to other scenarios. Recently, analysts have explored more advanced
approaches for using travel cost data in combination with contingent valuation data to estimate a
single joint model of individual's preferences and demand for a particular good or service
(Cameron,  1992). Future analysis is expected to also explore the use of travel cost information
and contingent valuation responses to estimate a random utility  or discrete-choice model. Jointly
soliciting contingent valuation responses with other data, such as travel cost data or site-select!on
data, both (1) expands  the ability of the model to account for both current users and non-users in
characterizing demand and (2) lends credibility to the contingent valuation information.

      Advantages

V   Can expand the applicability of existing valuation analyses.

X"   Potentially will allow for more complete characterization of demand by accounting for
      both current users of the resource and non-users.

      Disadvantages

V   The theoretical models and applied approaches for estimating demand using combined
      data are technically complex and not thoroughly developed.

X"   It is not clear how to reconcile data from the different approaches if they do not
      correspond well.
                                                                                Page 146

-------
Example of Combining Contingent Valuation and Travel Cost Data (Cameron, 1992)

In this study, Cameron combines contingent valuation responses and travel cost data on actual
behavior collected through a single survey instrument to estimate a joint model of individual's
preferences and demand for fishing days. The in-person survey, conducted by the Texas
Department of Parks and Wildlife, asked 3,366 respondents:

(1)     If they would have participated in salt-water fishing if their total annual cost was $X
       more, where the additional dollar amount was randomly chosen from $50 to $20,000;

(2)     How much they will spend on their current fishing trip; and

(3)     How many trips they took over the last year.

The estimated model of demand for fishing days was then used to value greater and lesser
restrictions on days of access. Specifically, Cameron estimated that a 10 percent reduction in
fishing days would result in a $35 loss in welfare, on average. The complete loss of access was
estimated to result in a $3,451 loss in welfare, on average.
References and Further Reading

Cameron, T.A. 1992. "Combining Contingent Valuation and Travel Cost Data for the Valuation
of Nonmarket Goods." Land Economics, August, 68(3): 302-17.

Freeman, A.M., III.  1993. The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values: Theory
and Methods. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future.

Mitchell, R.C. andR.T. Carson. 1989. Using Surveys to Value Public Goods:  The Contingent
Valuation Method. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future.

Roe, B., K. Boyle and M. F. Teisl.  1996. "Using Conjoint Analysis to Derive Estimates of
Compensating Variation." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 31(2): 145-
159.

Wittink, D.R. and P.  Cattin.  1989.  "Commercial Use of Conjoint Analysis: An Update."
Journal of Marketing, 53:91-96.
                                                                              Page 147

-------
6.3.8  Conjoint Analysis and Contingent Ranking
                                                                            Stated
                                                                          Preference
                                                                          Approach
This section introduces the reader to conjoint analysis, a technique applied fairly recently to the
valuation of environmental quality, and the more familiar approach of contingent ranking, which
actually represents one type of conjoint analysis.

Conjoint Analysis

Conjoint analysis is a technique developed by marketing analysts used to value consumer
preferences for specific features of goods or services. First, a composite good is separated into
its constituent attributes.  Then, individuals are surveyed regarding their relative preferences for
alternative bundles of attributes, with multiple attributes varying simultaneously.  The
information gathered from survey respondents can then be used to calculate the marginal rates of
substitution between the constituent attributes. By including price as one of the attributes, it is
possible to rescale the utility index in dollars and derive estimates of willingness-to-pay for
particular attribute bundles.

Conjoint analyses generally fall into one of three types: ranking (same as contingent ranking
approach discussed below), paired rating, and discrete choice.  In a ranking study, respondents
are often given several  cards. Each card shows a unique product or program composed of
specific attribute levels. Respondents are asked to put these cards in order — from their most
preferred to least preferred product or program. Alternatively, with the  pairwise rating
technique, respondents are shown two different products or programs simultaneously.
Respondents are asked  which product they prefer, and answer by supplying a rating within some
range of number, for example, 1 to 9, where 1 indicates a strong preference for the first program,
9 indicates a strong preference for the second program, and 5 indicates indifference  between the
two programs. Finally, the discrete choice technique provides respondents with several  different
products or programs simultaneously and simply asks them to identify the most-preferred
alternative in the choice set.

Conjoint analysis can be a useful technique in the valuation of improvements to ecological
resources, given that several service flows are often affected simultaneously.  For example,
improved water quality in a lake will  improve the quality of several services provided by the lake
such as a cleaner drinking water supply, increased fishing and boating usage, and increased
biodiversity.  Conjoint  analysis allows the valuation of these service flows both individually and
as a whole. The technique also allows respondents to systematically evaluate trade-offs between
multiple environmental attributes or between environmental and non-environmental attributes
(Johnson etal, 1995).
                                                                                 Page 148

-------
Example Conjoint Analysis Study (Mackenzie, 1992)

This study develops a conjoint measure approach to evaluate unpriced attributes for
recreational waterfowl hunting trips in Delaware. First, focus interviews were conducted
with various hunters to identify major attributes of hunting trips that influence trip
preferences. Four plausible levels were chosen for each of the following attributes:

•      Travel time (1, 2, 4, or 8 hours  each way)
       Trip cost per day ($25, $50, $100, or $200)
•      Type of hunting party (alone, with casual acquaintances, with  close friends, or with
       family)
       Site congestion (none, slight, moderate, heavy)
       Hunting success (none, one duck, three ducks, three ducks and one goose)
       Annual license fee (for state residents:  $15, $20, $25, or $30; else: $45, $50, $60, or
       $80)

A mailback survey questionnaire was designed to measure the relative preferences for these
attributes by asking respondents to rank trip options providing alternative levels of each of
the attributes. For example, respondents  may have been asked to choose between (1) a trip
with family to a slightly congested site two hours away, costing $100  per day, resulting in
three ducks and requiring a $20 license, and (2) a trip with close friends to a heavily
congested site one hour away, costing $25 per day, resulting in one duck and requiring a $15
license. The survey was administered in  1989 to 3,351  hunters who purchased Delaware
hunting licenses for the 1988-1989 hunting season.  The survey generated 1,384 usable
responses; of these, 696 respondents had  hunted waterfowl at least one day during
Delaware's 1988-1989 waterfowl season.

A logistic model was then used to model  these responses, and the marginal value of the
various trip attributes could be calculated. The implied value of ducks bagged, for example,
was found to be $81.35 per duck.  The value of travel time was found to be $37.07 per hour.
     Advantages

     Conjoint analysis allows the valuation of an action as a whole and the various attributes
     or effects of the action.

     Respondents are allowed to systematically evaluate trade-offs among multiple attributes.

     The trade-off process may encourage respondent introspection and facilitates consistency
     checks on response patterns (Johnson et a/., 1995).

     Respondents are generally more comfortable providing qualitative rankings or ratings of
     attribute bundles that include prices, rather than dollar valuations of the same bundles
     without prices. By de-emphasizing price as simply another attribute, the conjoint
     approach  minimizes many of the biases that can arise in open-ended contingent valuation

                                                                                Page 149

-------
       studies where respondents are presented with the unfamiliar and often unrealistic task of
       putting prices on non-market amenities (Mackenzie, 1992).

X"     Because the technique has been so widely used in marketing literature, many of the
       statistical issues in the design and analysis of this type of study have been resolved.

V     Allows for questions regarding how one resource might be traded-off against another
       resource (rather than estimating WTP in terms of dollars).

V     Allows for the assessment of situations where some attributes of a resource improve
       while other attributes decline.

       Disadvantages

V     Respondents may find some trade-offs difficult to evaluate or unfamiliar to them.

V     A large number of trade-off questions may frustrate respondents.

X"     Pairwise comparisons impose strict assumptions on preferences.

X"     Although conjoint analysis has been used widely in the field of market research, its
       validity and reliability for valuing non-market commodities is largely untested (Johnson
       etal., 1995).

V     If the number of attributes or levels of the attributes is increased, the sample size and/or
       the number of comparisons each respondent makes must be increased.

Contingent Ranking

Contingent ranking asks respondents to hypothetically rank alternative choices or bundles of
goods or services, where the alternatives vary in terms of their characteristics (e.g., representing
different qualities or quantities of a good or service  and different costs), in order of preference.
These rankings can be analyzed to determine each respondent's preferences for the various
attributes of the goods or services. If a monetary value can be assigned as one of the attributes,
then it is possible to compute the respondent's willingness-to-pay for the environmental quality
characteristic of the good or service on the basis of the ranking of the alternatives (Freeman,
1993).

One benefit of contingent ranking studies (compared to other contingent methods) is that
respondents  may be able to give more meaningful answers to questions about their behavior
(e.g., they prefer one alternative over another) rather than to direct questions about the value of a
good or service or the value of changes in environmental quality. The major challenge with
contingent ranking is how to translate the answers into a dollar value. It may be necessary to
imply a value from the relative ranking of other goods and services that do have a monetary
value, which may lead to greater uncertainty in the actual value that is placed on the good or
service of interest.
                                                                                 Page 150

-------
For example, contingent ranking could be used to value a proposed change in the environmental
quality of a recreational site. Respondents would be asked how they rank a set of sites that vary
in two or more characteristics, where one characteristic is distance and another is level of
environmental quality. Based on the ranking of the sites, the value of changes in environmental
quality could be implied based on how distance (and therefore, the cost of travel) is traded off for
other characteristics, including environmental quality (Mitchell and Carson, 1989).

       Advantages

X"     Respondents may be more comfortable ranking alternative options rather than answering
       a willingness-to-pay question.

       Disadvantages

V     Contingent ranking requires more sophisticated statistical techniques to estimate WTP.

X"     The respondents' behavior underlying the results of a contingent ranking study is not
       well understood.

X"     Contingent ranking tends to extract preferences in the form of attitudes instead of
       behavior intentions, and by only providing a limited number of options, it may force
       respondents to make choices that they would not  voluntarily make (Mitchell and Carson,
       1989).

References and Further Reading

Desvousges, W., V.K. Smith, and M.P. McGivney. 1983. A Comparison of Alternative
Approaches for Estimating Recreation and Related Benefits of Water Quality Improvement.
Prepared for the U.S.  EPA. EPA/230/05-83/001. Washington D.C.: U.S. EPA.

Freeman, A.M., III.  1993.  The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values:  Theory
and Methods. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future.

Johnson, F. R., W.H.  Desvousges, L.L. Wood, and E.E. Fries.  1995. Conjoint Analysis of
Individual and Aggregate Environmental Preferences, Technical Paper No. T-9502. Triangle
Economic Research.

Mackenzie, J.  1992.  "Evaluating Recreation Trip Attributes and Travel Time via Conjoint
Analysis." Journal of Leisure Research 24(2): 171-184.  National Recreation and Park
Association.

Mitchell, R.C.  andR.T. Carson.  1989. Using Surveys to Value Public Goods: The Contingent
Valuation Method. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future.

U.S. EPA, RTI. 1983. A Comparison of Alternative Approaches for Estimating Recreation and
Related Benefits of Water Quality Improvements, EPA Document 230-05-83-001 Under
Cooperative Agreement #68-01-5838. Washington D.C.: U.S. EPA.

                                                                               Page 151

-------
Page 152

-------
6.3.9  Benefits Transfer
Benefits transfer is often used in benefit-cost analysis when limited resources or time constraints
make it difficult to conduct an original valuation study. Benefits transfer involves obtaining an
existing estimate of an economic use value (e.g., unit willingness-to-pay per individual) or
demand function from a previous study to estimate the value associated with a similar use being
provided by a similar ecological resource under another policy case or at a new study site. The
benefit estimate from the original valuation study is scaled by the level of change under the new
policy case or level of use  at the new study site (e.g., number of users) to estimate the benefits of
a similar change in the services provided by the ecological resource under study.

Benefits transfer is most reliable when (U.S. EPA, 1995):

•      The original policy case or site and the new policy case or study site are very similar;

•      The environmental change is very similar for the original  and new analyses; and

       The original valuation study was carefully conducted and used sound valuation
       techniques.

The reliability of the benefits estimate developed using the benefit transfer technique depends
primarily on the similarity between the original and the new policy case or study site.  With
respect to benefits transfer between sites, large differences in quality, location, visitor
characteristics,  availability of substitutes, or object of valuation between the original and the new
site have been found to impact the reliability of the benefit estimates derived through benefit
transfer (Kirchhoff et al., 1997).

There are three commonly used benefit transfer techniques:

•      Mean unit value transfer;

•      Adjusted unit value transfer; and

•      Benefit/demand function or model transfer.

When possible, the transfer of demand functions or models is generally preferred to the use of
unit value estimates.  Both Loomis (1992) and Kirchhoff et al.  (1997) conducted empirical
analyses that found the transfer of a benefit or demand function was more reliable (e.g.,  smaller
percentage errors) than a unit value transfer approach.

Mean Unit Value Transfer

Average unit values are generally used in benefits transfer analysis when either the demand
function or model used for the original study is unavailable or the input data for a demand
function or model is not available for the new policy case or study site. Average unit values are
often used for regulatory analysis because the broad, typically regional or national, scope of the
analyses makes it impossible, and often inappropriate, to reestimate a demand function or model

                                                                                 Page 153

-------
developed for a specific location.  The mean unit value technique assumes that the use value of a
resource change under the original policy case or at the original site can be applied directly to the
new policy case or site without adjustment. In this case, the unit value estimates generally apply
to a specific use of the resource (e.g., recreational fishing, duck hunting, fresh water swimming)
and represent an average or median value developed from a wide range of studies.

Adjusted Unit Value Transfer

The unit value estimate may be adjusted before it is applied to the new study situation to correct
for any bias or inaccuracies associated with the original valuation study or to adjust for
differences in the attributes of the policy case or study site that would affect the value estimate.
Under the adjusted unit value technique, adjustments are generally made to account for three
types of differences between the original and the new policy case or study site (U.S. EPA,  1995):

•      Differences in attributes of the policy case or site, level of use, or in the socioeconomic
       characteristics of users affected by the change;

       Differences in the environmental policy, change, or resulting effects; and

•      Differences in the availability of substitute goods and services.

Additional adjustments may also be made to the nominal value from the original study(ies) to
update the value estimate to current year dollars.  If the benefits transfer application is using
multiple primary valuation studies from different study years, the estimates will need to be
converted to the same year dollars to allow comparisons to be made.

Benefit/Demand Function or Model Transfer

A final option under benefits transfer is to transfer the entire demand function or valuation
method estimated by another valuation study to the new policy case or study site. In most
circumstances, as with transferring a unit value estimate, the demand function may need to be
adjusted to better suit the characteristics of the new policy case or study site. The transferred
demand function can then be used to estimate the willingness-to-pay or benefits associated with
improving the service provided by the ecological resource. When the demand function is
transferred, the benefit estimate captures both changes in the level of use and unit value benefit
estimate for the new study site (Loomis, 1992). Recent research suggests that when conducting
a benefits transfer analysis for a new study site, benefit or demand functions that account for a
larger number of site characteristics may provide for more accurate benefit transfer analysis
(Kirchhoff et a/.,  1997). Unfortunately, the use of more detailed benefit or demand functions
increases the need to collect site-specific data for both the original study site and the new study
site (or policy-specific data in case of a benefits transfer analysis for a new policy case), which
increases the time and resource costs of benefits transfer analysis.

Models for valuing ecological resources and damages to ecological resources can also be
transferred in their entirety.  Any valuation model being considered should be evaluated to
determine its applicability to the new study situation, much in the same way as a unit value
                                                                                  Page 154

-------
estimate or demand function must be reviewed for appropriateness before it is used to estimate
the value of a change in a service under a different policy case or at a different site.

       Advantages

V    Economic benefits can be estimated more quickly than if undertaking an original
       valuation study.

V    Benefits transfer is typically less costly than conducting an original valuation study.

X"    Can be used as a screening technique to determine if a more detailed, original valuation
       study should be conducted.

       Disadvantages

X"    It may be difficult or impossible to find high-quality, well-documented original studies
       from which to obtain unit value estimates that can be appropriately applied to the new
       study site. The use of lower quality unit value estimates will adversely affect the
       accuracy and reliability of the benefit transfer analysis.

V    Unit value estimates can quickly become dated.
Example Benefits Transfer Study (Bowen etal, 1993; U.S. EPA, 1995)

In order to estimate the value of recreational fishing in Massachusetts Bays, Bowen et al.
reviewed several studies of different types of marine recreational fishing experiences, largely
using the travel cost model. They chose to use estimates reported by Rowe (1985) ranging from
$13 to $104 (1981  dollars) per fishing day. They then inflated these estimates to 1989 dollars
($18 to $142) and applied them to the 2.5 million marine recreational fishing trips estimated to
have been taken in the Massachusetts Bays region in 1989.  This calculation yielded a net benefit
value range of all recreational fishing trips in the Massachusetts Bays of $45 to $355 million.

This estimate is only reliable as an indication of the order of magnitude of the likely net
recreational fishing benefits generated by the Bays, because the data on the number of trips
conducted in the Bays system are subject to considerable uncertainty. In addition,  an assumption
was made that the range of recreational  fishing values developed in a variety of different settings
for a variety of different species reported by Rowe are applicable to the Bays system.  The use of
fishing day values from these other studies to value Massachusetts Bays recreation is also subject
to criticism because of the use of estimates from a distinctly different geographic region.
                                                                                  Page 155

-------
References and Further Reading

Bingham, T., et al., eds. 1992.  Proceedings of the Association of Environmental and Resource
Economists (AERE) Conference on Benefits Transfers.  Washington D.C.

Bowen, R.E., J.H. Archer, D.G. Terkla, and J.C. Myers. 1993.  The Massachusetts Bays
Management System: A Valuation of Bays Resources and Uses and an Analysis of its
Regulatory and Management Structure.  Boston, Massachusetts: Massachusetts Bays Program.

Boyle, KJ. and J.C. Bergstrom. 1992. "Benefits Transfer Studies: Myths, Pragmatism, and
Dealism."  Water Resources Research 28: 657-663.

Desvousges, W.H., M.C. Naughton, and G.R. Parsons.  1992.  "Benefit Transfer: Conceptual
Problems in Estimating Water Quality Benefits Using Existing Studies." Water Resources
Research 28: 675-683.

Downing, M. and T.  Ozuna, Jr.  1994. Testing the Reliability of the Benefit Function Transfer
Approach. Oak Ridge, Tennessee: Environmental Sciences Division, Oak Ridge Laboratory.

Kirchhoff, S., E.G. Colby, and  J.T. LaFrance.  1997. "Evaluating the Performance of Benefit
Transfer: An Empirical Inquiry." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 33(1):
75-93.

Krupnick, A.J. 1993. "Benefits Transfers and Valuation of Environmental Improvements."
Resources.

Loomis, J.B.  1992.  "The Evolution of a More Rigorous Approach to Benefit Transfer: Benefit
Function Transfer."  Water Resources Research 28(3): 701-705.

Morey, E.R.  "What Is Consumer Surplus per Day of Use, When Is it Content Independent of the
Number of Days of Use, and What Does it Tell Us about Consumer's Surplus?" Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management 26: 257-270.

Opaluch J.J. and M.J. Mazzotta. 1992. "Fundamental Issues in Benefit Transfer and Natural
Resource Damage Assessment." in Benefits Transfer: Procedures, Problems, and Research
Needs. Snowbird, Utah: Workshop Proceedings, Association of Environmental and Resource
Economists.

Rowe, R.W.  1985. Valuing Marine Recreational Fishing on the Pacific Coast. La Jolla,
California: National Marine Fisheries Service, Southwest Fisheries Center.

Smith, V.K.  1992. "On Separating Defensible Benefit Transfers from Smoke and Mirrors."
Water Resources Research 28:  685-694.

U.S. EPA, Oceans and Coastal  Protection Division. 1995. Assessing the Economic Value of
Estuary Resources and Resource Services in Comprehensive Conservation and Management
                                                                              Page 156

-------
Plan (CCMP) Planning and Implementation, A National Estuary Program Environmental
Valuation Handbook.  Washington, D.C.: U.S. EPA.
                                                                             Page 157

-------
7.0  ISSUES AFFECTING THE ECONOMIC VALUATION OF

      ECOLOGICAL BENEFITS	


This section identifies and briefly discusses some additional issues that should be addressed by
an economic benefit analysis. These issues include:

•     uncertainty and variability;
•     discounting; and
•     equity.

Please refer to EPA's (2000) Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses and the other
references provided for a complete treatment of these topics.

7.1   UNCERTAINTY AND VARIABILITY

The variability and uncertainty associated with specific estimates is an important consideration
in a thorough benefits assessment. As EPA's (2000) Guidelines note, the issue is "not how to
avoid uncertainty, but how to account for it and present useful conclusions to those making
policy decisions."

Variability and uncertainty are inherent to ecological and economic assessment, stemming from
multiple potential sources including estimating the effect of the policy, modeling the fate and
transport of a pollutant (e.g., air modeling), estimating effects, and valuing the effects (or
changes in the effects). Variability and uncertainty arise from the inherent variation of natural
processes as well as from limited knowledge  about the many relationships between emissions
and exposures and effects.

To assess and present uncertainty, EPA (2000) instructs the analyst to:

      Present outcomes or conclusions based on expected or most plausible values;

•     Provide descriptions of all known key assumptions, biases, and omissions;

•     Perform sensitivity analyses for key assumptions; and

      Justify the assumptions used in the  sensitivity analysis.

If this initial assessment of uncertainty is not sufficient, then a more sophisticated analysis is
required. The appropriate approach depends  on the objectives of the analysis and the needs of
the decisionmakers.  Uncertainty and variability might be addressed by:

•     Using Monte Carlo analyses or other probabilistic techniques to estimate a probability
      distribution for the output (e.g., benefits);
                                                                            Page 158

-------
       Discussing and/or incorporating expert judgement regarding the potential range of effects
       and/or benefits (e.g., Delphi methods); or

•      Using meta-analysis to combine estimates of inputs (e.g., risks, values) or outputs (e.g.,
       benefits estimates) from multiple studies.

Accounting for uncertainty and variability can provide a more complete characterization of the
distribution of benefits than point-estimates. Nonetheless, many sources of uncertainty will
likely remain unquantified.  Any remaining omissions, biases, and data gaps should be described
qualitatively.

7.2    DISCOUNTING

When the benefits of an action accrue over time, such as with lagged and/or cumulative effects,
the role and importance of discounting needs to be considered in the context of the benefits
assessment. The discount rate used and time period for comparison can have significant effects
on the magnitude of the benefits estimate and the conclusions of the benefits assessment,
especially if benefits and costs occur in different points in time.  Discounting can be applied to
monetary values as well as quantitative assessments of benefits.

Traditionally, present value costs and benefits have been calculated using the shadow price of
capital or the consumption rate of interest as the discount rate. These may be appropriate or
inappropriate discount rates, depending on the assumptions made regarding the flow of capital
and the value of future consequences (e.g., are future values adjusted upward to reflect increased
value due to increased scarcity). Furthermore, a different discount rate (or  even no discounting)
might be appropriate for inter-generational effects. With respect to the time period of
comparison, the analysis might choose to translate future values into present ones — the
traditional approach — or alternatively, annualize costs and benefits or accumulate benefits (and
costs) forward to some future time period.

Chapter 6 of EPA's (2000) Guidelines provides a lengthy and detailed discussion of discounting
as well as numerous references for further reading on this topic.

7.3    DISTRIBUTIONAL AND EQUITY ANALYSES

Distributional and equity analyses examine the realized impacts  or improvements across
different sectors of society.  Determinations regarding whether a policy or action is "equitable"
rely on ethical and moral principles, rather than economic principles.  In measuring changes in
social welfare, economists most often implicitly assume that the welfare of all individuals is
weighted equally. This assumption implies that if a positive change, or benefit, experienced by a
wealthier individual is determined to be greater in value than the cost, or negative effect,
experienced by a poorer person, social welfare is said to be "improved" by  the change.
However, such a change may not be "equitable" from an ethical  or moral perspective.

To support a distributional or equity analysis, an ecological benefit analysis should provide
information on the distribution of costs and benefits (i.e., track who in society is benefitting from
                                                                                 Page 159

-------
the change and who is not) in addition to the total or net benefit estimate. The elements of a
distributional or equity analysis include:

•      Identifying the groups and entities of concern (e.g., race, income) for an equity
       evaluation;

       Ensuring that data are developed for the groups and entities of concern; and

       Estimating the distribution of changes across each group and entity of concern.

Decisionmakers then use the results of the distributional or equity analysis, along with the results
of the ecological benefit analysis, other analyses conducted, and moral, legal, and/or
philosophical considerations to evaluate the proposed policy or action.

Chapter 9 of EPA's (2000) Guidelines provides a lengthy and detailed discussion of
distributional analyses as well as numerous references for further reading on this topic.

References and Further Reading

Arnold, F.S. 1995. Economic Analysis of Environmental Policy and Regulation.  John Wiley
and Sons, Inc. New York, New York.

Freeman, A. M. III.  1993. The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values: Theory
and Methods. Resources for the Future. Washington, DC.

Morgan, M.G. and M. Henri on. 1990.  Uncertainty: Dealing with  Uncertainty in Quantitative
Risk and Policy Analysis.  Cambridge University Press. New York, New York.

U.S. EPA.  1997.  Discounting in Environmental Policy Evaluation, Draft Final Report.
Prepared by Frank Arnold, Fran Sussman, and Leland Deck for the U.S. EPA, Office of Policy,
Planning, and Evaluation. April 1, 1997.

U.S. EPA.  1997.  Evaluating the Equity of Environmental Policy Options Based on the
Distribution of Economic Effects, Draft. Prepared for U.S. EPA, Office of Policy, Planning, and
Evaluation. May 23,  1997.

U.S. EPA.  1997.  Technical Assistance on a Review and Evaluation of Procedures Used to
Study Issues of Uncertainty in the Conduct of Economic Cost-Benefit Research and Analysis,
Draft Report. Prepared by Hagler Bailly Consulting, Incorporated for the U.S. EPA, Office of
Policy, Planning, and Evaluation.  May 27, 1997.

U.S. EPA. 2000. Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses. U.S.  EPA, Office of the
Administrator. EPA/240/R-00/003. September.
                                                                                Page 160

-------
8.0  REFERENCES
8.1    ECOLOGICAL REFERENCES AND FURTHER READING

Allen, T.F. and Hoekstra, T.W.  1992.  Toward a Unified Ecology.  Complexity in Ecological
Systems Series. New York, NY: Columbia University Press.

Ankley, G.T.; Thomas, N.A.; Di Toro, D.M.; et al.  1994. Assessing potential bioavailability of
metals in sediments: a proposed approach. Environ. Manage. 18: 331-337.

Bartell, S.M., R.H. Gardner, and R.V. O'Neill.  1992. Ecological Risk Estimation. Boca Raton,
FL: Lewis Publishers.

Beyer, W.N.; Heinz, G.H.; Redmon-Norwood, A.R. (eds.).  1996. Environmental Contaminants
in Wildlife:  Interpreting Tissue Concentrations.  A Special Publication of the Society of
Environmental Toxicology and Chemistry (SETAC), La Point, T.W. (series ed.).  Boca Raton,
FL: CRC Press, Inc., Lewis Publishers.

Bingham, G., R. Bishop, M. Brody, D. Bromley, E. Clark, W. Cooper, R. Costanza, T. Hale, G.
Hay den, S. Kellert, R. Norgaard, B. Norton, J. Payne, C. Russell, and G. Suter. 1995. "Issues in
Ecosystem Valuation:  Improving Information for Decision Making." Ecological Economics 14:
73-90.

Briand, F., and Cohen, I.E. 1987. Environmental correlates of food chain length. Science 238:
956-960.

Brown, J.H. and Lomolino, M.V.  1998. Biogeography. 2nd Ed.  Sunderland, MA: Sinauer
Associates, Inc. Publishers.

Cairns, J. Jr.; Niederlehner, B.R. 1995. Ecological Toxicity Testing: Scale, Complexity, and
Relevance. Boca Raton, FL:  CRC Press, Inc., Lewis Publishers.

Calabrese, E.J.; Baldwin, L.A. 1993. Performing Ecological Risk Assessments.  New York, NY:
Lewis Publishers.

Calow, P. (ed.). 1993. Handbook ofEcotoxicology, Volume 1. Boston, MA: Blackwell
Publishers.

Cochran, W.G. 1977.  Sampling Techniques. 3rd ed. New York, NY: John Wiley and Sons,
Inc.

Cochran, W.G.; Cox, G.M. 1957. Experimental Design. New York, NY: Wiley.

Cockerham, L.G.; Shane, B.S. (eds.). 1994. Basic Environmental Toxicology. Boca Raton, FL:
CRC Press, Inc., Lewis Publishers.

                                                                            Page 161

-------
Cooke, A.S. 1971.  Selective predation by newts on frog tadpoles treated with DDT.  Nature
229: 275-276.

Costanza, R., R. d'Arge, R. de Groot, S. Farber, M. Grasso, B. Hannon, K. Limburg, S. Naeem,
R.V. O'Neill, J. Paruelo, R.G. Raskin, P. Sutton, and M. van den Belt. 1988. The value of the
world's ecosystem services and natural capital.  Ecological Economics 25(1):3-15.

Costanza, R.; Cumberland, J.; Daly, H.; Goodland, R.; and Norgaard, R. 1997. An Introduction
to Ecological Economics.  Boca Raton, FL: St. Lucie Press.

Costanza, R.; Low, B.S.; Ostrom, E.;  and Wilson,  J.  (eds.). 2001. Institutions, Ecosystems, and
Sustainability.  Ecological Economics Series. Boca Raton, FL: Lewis Publishers.

Davis, W.S.; Simon, T.P.  1995.  Biological Assessment and Criteria:  Tools for Water Resource
Planning and Decision Making.  Boca Raton, FL:  CRC Press, Inc., Lewis Publishers.

Daily, G.C. (ed).  1997.  Nature 's Services: Societal Dependence on Natural Ecosystems.
Washington, DC: Island Press.

Daily, G.C., S. Alexander, P.R. Ehrlich, L. Goulder, J. Lubchenco, P.A. Matson, H.A.  Mooney,
S. Postel, S. H. Shneider, D. Tilman, and G.M. Woodwell.  1997.  Ecosystem services: benefits
supplied to human societies by natural ecosystems. Ecological Society of America, Issues in
Ecology, Number 2,  Spring 1997.

DeBellevue, E.B., T. Maxwell, R. Costanza, and M.  Jacobsen. 1993. "Development of a
Landscape Model for the Patuxent River Watershed."  Discussion Paper #10, Maryland
International Institute for Ecological Economics, Solomons, MD.

ESA Ad Hoc Committee on Ecosystem Management.  1995.  The Scientific Basis for Ecosystem
Management. Washington, DC: Ecological Society of America.

Fitz, H.C., R. Costanza, and E. Reyes. 1993. The Everglades Landscape Model (ELM):
Summary Report of Task 2, Model Development. Report to the South Florida Water
Management District, Everglades Research Division.

Fitz, H.C., E.B. DeBellevue, R. Costanza, R. Boumans, T. Maxwell, L. Wainger, and F. Sklar.
1995. "Development of a General Ecosystem Model (GEM) for a Range of Scales and
Ecosystems. Ecological Modeling (in press).

Foran, J.A. and Ferenc,  S.A. (eds.). 1999. Multiple  Stressors in Ecological Risk and Impact
Assessment. A Special Publication of SET AC.  Pensacola, FL: Society of Environmental
Toxicology and Chemistry.

Freedman, B. 1989. Environmental Ecology.  The Impacts of Pollution and Other Stresses on
Ecosystem Structure and Function.  New York, NY: Academic Press.

Gotelli, NJ. 1998.  A Primer of Ecology.  2nd Ed.  Sunderland, MA: Sinauer Associates Inc.

                                                                              Page 162

-------
Green, R.H. 1979. Sampling Design and Statistical Methods for Environmental Biologists.
New York, NY: Wiley.

Gulland, J.A. 1977. Fish Population Dynamics. London, UK: John Wiley & Sons.

Hall, S. 1; Raffaelli, D. G. 1993. Food web: theory and reality.  In: Begon, M.; Fritter, A. H.,
eds. Advances in Ecological Research, Vol. 24. San Diego, CA: Academic Press; pp. 187-239.

Hairston, N.G. Jr., Hairston, N.G. Sr. 1993. Cause-effect relationships in energy flow, trophic
structure, and interspecific interactions. Am. Nat. 142: 379-411.

Hamelink, J.L.; Landrum, P.F.; Bergman, H.L.; Benson, W.H. (eds). 1994. Bioavailability:
Physical, Chemical, and Biological Interactions. Boca Raton, FL:  CRC Press, Inc., Lewis
Publishers.

Hoffman, D.J.; Rattner, B.A.; Burton, G.A. Jr.; Cairns, J., Jr. (eds.). 1995. Handbook of
Ecotoxicology. Ann Arbor, MI:  CRC Press, Inc., Lewis Publishers.

Hugget, R.J.; Kimerle, R.A.; Mehrle, P.M., Jr.; Bergman, H.L.  1992. Biomarkers:
Biochemical, Physiological, and Histological Markers of Anthropogenic Stress.  A Special
Publication of the Society of Environmental Toxicology and Chemistry (SETAC), Ward, C.H.;
Walton, B.T; La Point, T.W. (series eds.). Boca Raton, FL:  CRC Press, Inc., Lewis Publishers.

Kabata-Pendias, A.; Pendias H. 1984. Trace Elements in Soils and Plants. Boca Raton, FL:
CRC Press, Inc.

Kendall, R.J.; Lacher, T.E. (eds.). 1994. Wildlife Toxicology and Population Modeling:
Integrated Studies ofAgroecosystems. A Special Publication of the Society of Environmental
Toxicology and Chemistry (SETAC), La Point, T.W. (series ed.). Boca Raton, FL: CRC Press,
Inc., Lewis Publishers.

Klemm, D.J.; Lewis, P. A.; Fulk, F.; Lazorchak, J.M. 1990.  Macroinvertebrate Field and
Laboratory Methods for Evaluating the Biological Integrity of Surface Waters. Washington,
DC:  U.S. EPA. EPA/600/4-90/030.

Krebs, C.J.  1978. Ecology: The Experimental Analysis of Distribution and Abundance; Second
Edition. New York, NY: Harper & Row.

Landis, W.G.; Yu, M.  1995. Introduction to Environmental Toxicology: Impacts of Chemicals
upon Ecological Systems.  Boca Raton, FL: CRC Press, Inc., Lewis Publishers.

Landis, W.G.; Hughes, J.S.; Lewis, M.A. (eds.).  1993.  Environmental Toxicity and Risk
Assessment. Philadelphia, PA: American Society for Testing and Materials.

MacArthur, R.H., and Wilson, E.O.  1963.  An equilibrium theory of insular biogeography.
Evolution 17: 373-387.
                                                                               Page 163

-------
MacArthur, R.H., and Wilson, E.O.  1967.  The Theory of Island Biogeography. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.

Margalef, R.  1968. Perspectives in Ecological Theory. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago
Press.

Maughan, J.T. 1993. Ecological Assessment of Hazardous Waste Sites. New York, NY:  Van
Nostrand Reinhold.

Moltmann, J.F.; Rombke, J.  1996.  AppliedEcotoxicology. Boca Raton, FL:  CRC Press, Inc.,
Lewis Publishers.

National Research Council (NRC).  1994. Science and Judgment in Risk Assessment.
Washington, DC: National Academy Press.

National Research Council (NRC).  1993. Issues in Risk Assessment. Washington, DC:
National Academy Press.

National Research Council (NRC).  1983. Risk Assessment in the Federal Government:
Managing the Process.  Washington, DC: National Academy Press.

Neilson, A.H.  1994. Organic Chemicals in the Aquatic Environment: Distribution,
Persistence, and Toxicity.  Boca Raton, FL: CRC Press, Inc., Lewis Publishers.

Newman, M.C. 1995.  Quantitative Methods in Aquatic Ecotoxicology. Boca Raton, FL:  CRC
Press, Inc., Lewis Publishers.

Newman, M.C.; Mclntosh, A. W. (eds.).  1991. Metal Ecotoxicology: Concepts and
Applications.  Boca Raton, FL:  CRC Press, Inc., Lewis Publishers.

Norse, E. 1990.  Threats to Biological Diversity in the United States. Report prepared for the
U.S. EPA, Washington, DC, by Industrial Economics, Contract No. 68-W8-0038, Work
Assignment 115.

Noss, R.P.; LaRoe, E.T.; ans Scott,  J.M.  1995. Endangered Ecosystems of the United States: A
Preliminary Assessment of Loss and Degradation. Washington, DC: U.S. Department of the
Interior, National Biological Service.

Odum, E.P., in collaboration with H.T.Odum.  1959. Fundamentals of Ecology. Philadelphia,
PA: Saunders.

Ostrander, G. (ed.).  1996. Handbook of Aquatic Toxicology Methods. Boca Raton, FL:  CRC
Press, Inc., Lewis Publishers.

Ott, W.R. 1995. Environmental Statistics and Data Analysis.  Boca Raton, FL: CRC Press,
Inc., Lewis Publishers.
                                                                               Page 164

-------
Parker, S.P. (ed.). 1994. Dictionary of Scientific and Technical Terms; Fifth Edition. New
York, NY: McGraw-Hill.

Pimentel, D.  1988. Economic benefits of natural biota. Ecological Economics 25(l):45-47.

Pimm, S.L. 1980. Properties of food webs. Ecology 61: 219-225.

Pimm, S.L. 1982. Food Webs. New York, NY: Chapman and Hall

Principe, P.P. 1995. Ecological benefits assessment: A policy-oriented alternative to regional
ecological risk assessment. Human and Ecological Risk Assessment l(4):423-435.

Rand, G.M.; Petrocelli,  S.R. 1985. Fundamentals of Aquatic Toxicology. Methods and
Applications.  New York, NY: McGrawHill.

Renzoni, A.; Fossi, M.C.; Lari, L.; Mattel, N. (eds.). 1994. Contaminants in the Environment.
A Multidisciplinary Assessment of Risks to Man and Other Organisms.  Boca Raton, FL: CRC
Press, Inc., Lewis Publishers.

Ricklefs, R.E. 1990. Ecology; Second Edition. New York, NY: W.H. Freeman.

Scodari, P. 1992. Wetland Protection Benefits. Draft Report. Prepared for U.S. EPA, Office of
Policy, Planning, and Evaluation under Grant No.  CR-817553-01. October.

Stephan, C.E., Mount, D.I., Hanson, D.J., Gentile, J.H.,  Chapman, G.A., and Brungs. W.A.
1985. Guidelines for Deriving Numeric National Water Quality Criteria for the Protection of
Aquatic Organisms and Their Uses. Duluth, Minnesota: U.S. EPA. NTIS No. PB85-227049.

Sullivan, T.F. 1993. Environmental Regulatory Glossary. Government Institutes, Inc.

Suter, G.W. II.  1993. Ecological Risk Assessment. Boca Raton, FL:  Lewis Publishers.

Suter, G.W. II.  1989. "Ecological Endpoints." in Warren-Hicks, W., B.R. Parkhurst, and S.S.
Baker, Jr., eds. Ecological Assessment of Hazardous Waste Sites: A Field and Laboratory
Reference Document. EPA Document 600/3-89/013.  Corvallis Environmental Research
Laboratory, Oregon.

Suter, G. W., Efroymson, R.A., Sample, B.E., Jones, D.S. 2000. Ecological Risk Assessment for
Contaminated Sites. Boca Raton, FL: Lewis Publishers.

Terborgh, J.  1989. Where Have All the Birds Gone? Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Trapp, S.; McFarlane, J.C. (eds.).  1995.  Plant Contamination: Modeling and Simulation of
Organic Chemical Processes. Boca Raton, FL: CRC Press, Inc., Lewis Publishers.
                                                                               Page 165

-------
U.S. Department of the Interior (U.S. DOT).  1987.  Guidance on Use of Habitat Evaluation
Procedures and Suitability Index Models for CERCLA Application. Washington, DC: U.S. Fish
and Wildlife Service, National Ecology Center; PB86-100151.

U.S. EPA.  1983. Environmental Effects of Regulatory Concern Under TSCA: A Position
Paper. Washington, DC:  Office of Toxic Substances, Health and Environmental Review
Division (Author: Clements, R.G.)

U.S. EPA.  1986. Guidelines for Deriving Numerical Criteria for the Protection of Aquatic
Organisms and Their Uses.  Washington, DC: Office of Water Regulations and Standards.

U.S. EPA.  1986. Guidelines for the Health Risk Assessment of Chemical Mixtures.
Washington, DC: Office of Health and Environmental Assessment; EPA/600/8-87/045.

U.S. EPA.  1986. Quality Criteria for Water 198 6. Washington, DC: Office of Water
Regulations and Standards; EPA/440/5-86/001.

U.S. EPA.  1988. Superfund Exposure Assessment Manual. Washington, DC:  Office of Solid
Waste and Emergency  Response Directive 9285.5-1; EPA/540/1-88/001.

U.S. EPA.  1989. Ecological Assessment of Hazardous Waste Sites: A Field and Laboratory
Reference.  Corvallis, OR:  Office of Research and Development, Environmental Research
Laboratory; EPA/600/3-89/013.

U.S. EPA.  1989. Rapid Bioassessment Protocols for Use in Streams and Rivers:  Benthic
Macroinvertebrates and Fish.  Washington, DC:  Office of Water; EPA/444/4-89/001 (Authors:
Plafkin, J.L.; Barbour,  M.T.; Porter, K.D.; Gross, S.K.; Hughes, R.M.).

U.S. EPA.  1989. Risk Assessment Guidance for Superfund: Volume 2 - Environmental
Evaluation Manual, Interim Final. Washington, DC: Office of Solid Waste and Emergency
Response; EPA/540/1-89/001A.

U.S. EPA.  1989. Scoping Study of the Effects of Soil Contamination on Terrestrial Biota.
Washington, DC: Office of Toxic Substances.

U.S. EPA.  1989. Superfund Exposure Assessment Manual — Technical Appendix: Exposure
Analysis of Ecological Receptors.  Athens, GA: Office of Research and Development,
Environmental Research Laboratory (December).

U.S. EPA.  1990. Biological Criteria, National Program Guidance for Surface Waters.
Washington, DC: Office of Water Regulations and Standards; EPA/440/5-90/004.

U.S. EPA.  1990. Ecosystem Services and Their Valuation.  Prepared by RCG/Hagler, Bailly,
Inc., for the Office of Policy, Planning, and Evaluation.  Washington, DC:  U.S. EPA.

U.S. EPA.  1990. Managing Contaminated Sediments:  EPA Decision-Making Processes.
Washington, DC: Sediment Oversight Technical Committee; EPA/506/6-90/002.

                                                                               Page 166

-------
U.S. EPA. 1990. National guidance: wetlands and nonpoint source control programs.
Memorandum from Martha G. Prothro, Director, Office of Water Regulations and Standards;
Washington, DC: Office of Water (June 18).

U. S. EPA. 1991. Assessment and Control ofBioconcentratable Contaminants in Surface
Waters. June 1989 Draft prepared by U.S. EPA's National Effluent Toxicity Assessment Center,
Environmental Research Laboratory - Duluth, MN. Washington, DC:  Office of Water
Regulations and Standards; and Cincinnati, OH: Office of Health Effects Assessment.

U.S. EPA. 1991. Ecological Exposure and Effects of Airborne Toxic Chemicals: An Overview.
Corvallis, OR: Office of Research and Development, Environmental Research Laboratory;
EPA/600/3-91/001.

U. S. EPA. 1991. Summary Report on Issues in Ecological Risk Assessment.  Washington, DC:
Risk Assessment Forum; EPA/625/3-91/018.

U. S. EPA. 1991. Technical Support Document for Water Quality-based Toxics Control.
Washington, DC: Office of Water; EPA/505/2-90/001.

U.S. EPA. 1991. The Watershed Protection Approach Framework Document. Office of
Wetlands, Oceans, and Watersheds.  Washington, DC: U.S. EPA.

U.S. EPA. 1992. Dermal Exposure -Principles and Applications; Final; Washington, DC:
Office of Health and Environmental Assessment; EPA/600/8-91/01 IB.

U.S. EPA. 1992. Developing a Work Scope for Ecological Assessments. ECO Update,
Intermittent Bulletin, Volume 1, Number 4. Washington, DC:  Office of Emergency and
Remedial Response, Hazardous Site Evaluation Division; Publ. 9345.0-051.

U.S. EPA. 1992. Framework for Ecological Risk Assessment.  Washington, DC: Risk
Assessment Forum; EPA/630/R-92/001.

U.S. EPA. 1992. Guidance on Risk Characterization for Risk Managers and Risk Assessors.
February 26 Memorandum from F. Henry Habicht II, Deputy Administrator, to U.S. EPA
Assistant Administrators and Regional Administrators. Washington, DC: Office of the Deputy
Administrator.

U.S. EPA. 1992. Guidelines for Exposure Assessment. Federal Register.  57: 22888-22938
(May  29).

U.S. EPA. 1992. Peer Review Workshop Report on a Framework for Ecological Risk
Assessment.  Washington, DC:  Risk Assessment Forum; EPA/625/3-91/022.

U.S. EPA. 1992. Report on the Ecological Risk Assessment Guidelines Strategic Planning
Workshop. Washington, DC: Risk Assessment Forum; EPA/630/R-92/002.
                                                                              Page 167

-------
U.S. EPA. 1992. Science Advisory Board's Review of the Draft Final Exposure Assessment
Guidelines (SAB Final Review Draft, August 1991). Washington, DC:  Science Advisory
Board; EPA/SAB/IAQC-92/015.

U.S. EPA, Office of Policy Planning and Evaluation.  1992. Biological Populations as
Indicators of Environmental Change. Washington, DC: U.S. EPA. EPA/230/R-92/011

U. S. EPA. 1993. A Guidebook to Comparing Risks and Setting Environmental Priorities.
Washington, DC: U.S. EPA. EPA/230/B-98/003.

U.S. EPA. 1993. A Review of Ecological Assessment Case Studies from a Risk Assessment
Perspective.  Washington, DC: Risk Assessment Forum; EPA/630/R-92/005.

U. S. EPA. 1993. Guidance for Planning for Data Collection in Support of Environmental
Decision Making Using the Data Quality Objectives Process.  Interim Final.  Quality Assurance
Management Staff; EPA QA/G-4.

U.S. EPA. 1993. Guidance for Specifying Management Measures for Sources of Nonpoint
Pollution in Coastal Waters. Office of Water. Washington, DC: U.S. EPA.  EPA/840/B-92/002.

U.S. EPA. 1993. Habitat Evaluation: Guidance for the Review of Environmental Impact
Assessment Documents.  Prepared by Dynamac Corporation for the Office of Federal Activities
under EPA Contract No. 68-CO-0070. January.

U. S. EPA. 1993. Wildlife Exposure Factors Handbook Volumes I and II.  Washington, DC:
Office of Research and Development; EPA/600/R-93/187ab.

U.S. EPA. 1994. A Review of Ecological Assessment Case Studies from a Risk Assessment
Perspective,  Volume II. Washington, DC: Office of Research and Development, Risk
Assessment Forum; EPA/630/R-94/003.

U.S. EPA. 1994. Background for NEPA Reviewers: Grazing on Federal Lands. Prepared by
Science  Applications International Corporation under EPA Contract No. 68-C8-0066. February.

U.S. EPA. 1994. Ecological Risk Assessment Issue Papers. Washington, DC: Office of
Research and Development, Risk Assessment Forum; EPA/630/R-94/009.

U.S. EPA. 1994. Establishing Background Levels. Quick Reference Fact Sheet.  Washington,
DC: Office of Solid Waste and Emergency Response.  OSWER Directive 9285.7-19FS.
Publication PB94-963313; EPA/540/F-94/030.

U.S. EPA. 1994. Guidance for the Data Quality Objectives Process; EPA QA/G-4.
Washington, DC: Quality Assurance Management  Staff; Final, September.

U.S. EPA. 1994. Managing Ecological Risks at EPA: Issues and Recommendations for
Progress. Prepared by M.E. Troyer and M.S. Brody.  Washington, DC: U.S. EPA. EPA/600/R-
94/183.

                                                                             Page 168

-------
U.S. EPA.  1994. Memorandum from Carol Browner, Administrator, to Assistant
Administrators concerning "Toward a Place-Driven Approach: The Edgewater Consensus on an
EPA Strategy for Ecosystem Protection. May 24.

U.S. EPA.  1994. Peer Review Workshop Report on Ecological Risk Assessment Issue Papers.
Washington, DC: Office of Research and Development, Risk Assessment Forum; EPA/630/R-
94/008.

U.S. EPA.  1994. Selecting and Using Reference Information in Superfund Ecological Risk
Assessments.  ECO Update, Intermittent Bulletin, Volume 2, Number 4. Washington, DC:
Office of Emergency and Remedial Response, Hazardous Site Evaluation Division; Publication
9345.101; EPA/540/F-94/050; NTIS PB94-963319.

U.S. EPA.  1994. Toward a Place-Driven Approach: The Edgewater Consensus on an EPA
Strategy for Ecosystem Protection. Ecosystem Protection Workgroup.  Washington, DC: U.S.
EPA. March 15 Draft.

U. S. EPA.  1995. Draft Science Policy Council Statement on EPA Policy:  Cumulative Risk
Framework, With a Focus on Improved Characterization of Risks for Multiple Endpoints,
Pathways, Sources, andStressors. Washington, DC: Science Policy Council.

U.S. EPA.  1995. Ecological Risk:  A Primer for Risk Managers. Washington, DC: U.S. EPA.
EPA/734/R-95/001.

U. S. EPA.  1995. Ecological Significance and Selection of Candidate Assessment Endpoints.
ECO Update, Intermittent Bulletin,  Volume 3, Number 1. Washington, DC: Office of
Emergency and Remedial Response, Hazardous Site Evaluation Division; Publication 9345.0-
11FSI; EPA/540/F-95/037; NTIS PB95-963323.

U.S. EPA.  1995. EPA Risk Characterization Policy. March 21 Memorandum from Carol
Browner, Administrator, to EPA staff. Washington, DC: Office of the Administrator.

U.S. EPA.  1995. Great Lakes Water Quality Initiative Technical Support Document for the
Procedure to Determine Bioaccumulation Factors. Washington, DC:  Office of Water, U.S.
EPA. EPA/820/B-95/005.

U.S. EPA.  1997. Guidance on Cumulative Risk Assessment.  Washington, DC: Science Policy
Council.

U.S. EPA.  1997. Priorities for Ecological Protection: An Initial List and Discussion Document
for EPA. EPA/600/S-97/002. Washington, DC: U.S. EPA.

U.S. EPA.  1998. Guidelines for Ecological Risk Assessment. EPA/630/R-95/002B.
Washington, DC: U.S. EPA.
                                                                              Page 169

-------
U.S. EPA. 2000.  Assessing the Neglected Ecological Benefits of Watershed Management
Practices: A Resource Book.  Prepared for the Assessment and Watershed Protection Division,
Office of Water by ICF Consulting.  Washington, DC: U.S. EPA. April.

U.S. EPA. 2001.  Risk Characterization Handbook. Memorandum from W. Michael McCabe,
Deputy Administrator, Office of the Administrator; Washington, DC:  Office of the
Administrator (January 10).

Wilcove, D.S.  1985.  Nest predation in forest tracts and the decline of migratory songbirds.
Ecology 66: 1211-1214.

Wilson, E.O. and Bossert, W.H.  1971.  A Primer of Population Biology.  Stamford, CT: Sinauer
Associates Inc. Publishers.
                                                                               Page 170

-------
8.2    ECONOMIC REFERENCES AND FURTHER READING

Adams, R.M. and T.D. Crocker. 1991.  "Materials Damages," in Braden, John B. and Charles D.
Kolstad, eds. 1991. Measuring the Demand for Environmental Quality. North-Holland,
Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers.

Ahearn, M.C. 1997. "Why Economists Should Talk to Scientists and What They Should Ask:
Discussion." Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, July, 29(1):  113-116.

Alberini, A. 1995.  "Optimal Designs for Discrete Choice Contingent Valuation Surveys:
Single-Bounded, Double-Bounded, and Bivariate Models." Journal of Environmental
Economics and Management, 28(3): 287-306.

Arnold, F.S. 1995. Economic Analysis of Environmental Policy and Regulation. John Wiley
and Sons, Inc. New York, New York.

Arrow, K., R. Solow, P.R. Portney, E.E. Learner, R. Radner, and H. Schuman.  1993.  "Report of
the NOAA Panel on Contingent Valuation." Federal Register, January 15, 58(10): 4601-4614.

Bateman, I.J. and K.G. Willis, Eds. 1998.  Valuing Environmental Preferences: Theory and
Practice of the Contingent Valuation Method in the U.S., E.U., and Developing Countries.
Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Bartik, T.J. 1988.  "Evaluating the Benefits of Non-marginal Reductions in Pollution Using
Information on Defensive Expenditures." Journal of Environmental Economics and
Management, 15: 111-127.

Bartik, T.J. 1988.  "Measuring the Benefits of Amenity Improvements in Hedonic Price
Models." Land Economics 64(2): 172-183.

Bayless, M.  1982.  "Measuring the Benefits of Air Quality Improvements:  A Hedonic Salary
Approach." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 9(2): 81-99.

Bertollo, P. 1998.  "Assessing Ecosystem Health in Governed Landscapes: A Framework for
Developing Core Indicators." Ecosystem Health 4(1): 33-51.

Bingham, T., et al,  eds.  1992. Proceedings of the Association of Environmental and Resource
Economists (AERE) Conference and Benefits Transfers. Washington, D.C.

Bishop, R.C. and T. A. Heberlein. 1979. "Measuring Values of Extramarket Goods: Are
Indirect Measures Biased?"  American Journal of Agricultural Economics, December: 926-929.

Bjornstad, D.J. and  J.R. Kahn, eds.  1996. The Contingent Valuation of Environmental
Resources: Methodological Issues and Research Needs. Brookfi eld, Vermont: Edgar Elgar
Publishing Ltd.
                                                                             Page 171

-------
Bockstael, N.E., K.E. McConnell, and I.E. Strand. 1991. "Recreation" in Braden, John B. and
Charles D. Kolstad, eds. Measuring the Demand for Environmental Quality. North-Holland,
Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers.

Bockstael, N.E., K.E. McConnell, and I. Strand. 1989. "A Random Utility Model for
Sportfishing:  Some Preliminary Results for Florida."  Marine Resource Economics 6: 245-260.

Bockstael, N.E., K.E. McConnell, and I.E. Strand. 1989. "Measuring the Benefits of
Improvements in Water Quality:  The Chesapeake Bay." Marine Resource Economics 6(1): 1-
18.

Bowen, R.E.,  J.H. Archer, D.G. Terkla, and J.C. Myers. 1993. The Massachusetts Bays
Management System: A Valuation of Bays Resources and Uses and an Analysis of its
Regulatory and Management Structure.  Boston, Massachusetts: Massachusetts Bays Program.

Boyle, KJ. and J.C. Bergstrom. 1992.  "Benefits Transfer Studies:  Myths, Pragmatism, and
Dealism."  Water Resources Research 28:  657-663.

Braden, J.B. and C.D. Kolstad, eds. 1991. Measuring the Demand for Environmental Quality.
North-Holland, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers.

Cameron, T.A. 1992. "Combining Contingent Valuation and Travel Cost Data for the Valuation
of Nonmarket Goods." Land Economics, August, 68(3): 302-17.

Carson, R.T. et al. 1996. "Was the NOAA Panel Correct About Contingent Valuation? "
Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future.

Cole, R.A., et al.  1996. Linkages Between Environmental Outputs and Human Services, IWR
Report 96-R-4. Prepared for U.S. Army Corps of Engineers, Evaluation of Environmental
Investment Research Program.

Cooper, J.C.  1993. "Optimal Bid Selection for Dichotomous Choice Contingent Valuation."
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 24(1): 25-40.

Cooper, J.C. and J. Loomis.  1992.  "Sensitivity  of Willingness to Pay to Bid Design in
Dichotomous Choice Contingent Valuation." Land Economics.,  68(2): 211-224.

Costanza, R. et al.  1991. "The Value of the World's Ecosystem Services and Natural Capital."
Nature 387: 253-260. May.

Cummings, R.C., D.  S. Brookshire, and W.D. Schulze, Eds. Valuing Environmental Goods: An
Assessment of the Contingent Valuation Method. Rowan and Allanheld Publishers,  Totowa, NJ.

Daily, G., ed.  1997.  Nature's Services: Societal Dependence on Natural Ecosystems.
Washington, D.C.: Island Press.
                                                                              Page 172

-------
Desvousges, W.H., M.C. Naughton, and G.R. Parsons.  1992.  "Benefit Transfer:  Conceptual
Problems in Estimating Water Quality Benefits Using Existing Studies." Water Resources
Research 28:  675-683.

Desvousges, W., V.K. Smith, and M.P. McGivney.  1983. A Comparison of Alternative
Approaches for Estimating Recreation and Related Benefits of Water Quality Improvement.
Prepared for the U. S. Environmental Protection Agency. Report 230-05-83-001. Washington
D.C.

Downing, M. and T.  Ozuna, Jr.  1994.  Testing the Reliability of the Benefit Function Transfer
Approach.  Oak Ridge, Tennessee: Environmental Sciences Division, Oak Ridge Laboratory.

Edwards, S.F. and G.D. Anderson. 1984.  "Land Use Conflicts in Coastal Zone: An Approach
for the Analysis of the Opportunity Costs of Protecting Coastal Resources." Journal of the
Northeastern Agricultural Economics Council 13(1): 78-81.

Englin, I.E., T.A. Cameron, R.E. Mendelsohn, G.A. Parsons, and S.A. Shankle.  1991.
Valuation of Damages to Recreational  Trout Fishing in the  Upper Northeast due to Acidic
Deposition. Richland, Washington: Pacific Northwest Laboratory. Prepared for National Acidic
Precipitation Assessment Program.

Ehrlich, P. and A. Ehrlich. 1997. Betrayal of Science and Reason. Island Press, Washington,
D.C.

Fletcher, J., W. Adamowicz, and T. Graham-Tomasi. 1990. "The Travel Cost Model of
Recreation Demand." Leisure Sciences 12: 119-147.

Freeman, A.M., III.  1993. The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values: Theory
and Methods. Washington, D.C.:  Resources for the Future.

Gramlich, Edward M. 1990. A Guide to Benefit-Cost Analysis, Second Edition.  Prentice Hall.

Haab, T.C.  and K.E.  McConnell. "Referendum Models and Negative Willingness to Pay:
Alternative Solutions." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 32(3): 251-270.

Hanemann, W.M.  1991 "Willingness to Pay and Willingness to Accept:  How Much Can They
Differ?" American Economic Review 81 (3): 635-647.

Hanemann, W.M.  1984. "Welfare Evaluations in Contingent Valuation Experiments with
Discrete Responses." American Journal of Agricultural Economics, August, 66:  332-341.

Haniey, N. and C.L.  Spash. 1993. Cost Benefit Analysis and the Environment. Brookfield,
Vermont: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.

Hanley, N., J.F. Shogren, and B. White.  1997. Environmental Economics in Theory and
Practice. Oxford University Press, New York, New York. p. 362-364, 395-396.
                                                                              Page 173

-------
Johnson, F.R., W.H. Desvousges, L.L. Wood, and E.E. Fries.  1995.  Conjoint Analysis of
Individual and Aggregate Environmental Preferences, Technical Paper No. T-9502. Triangle
Economic Research.

Just, R.E., D.L. Hueth, and A. Schmitz.  1982. Applied Welfare Economics and Public Policy.
Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall.

Kannimen, B.J.  1993. "Design of Sequential Experiments for Contingent Valuation Studies."
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 25(1): sl-sll.

 Kaoru, Y., V.K. Smith, and J.L. Liu.  1995.  "Using Random Utility Models to Estimate the
Recreational Value of Estuarine Resources." American Journal of Agricultural Economics,
February, 77: 141-151.

King, D.M.  1997.  Using Ecosystem Assessment Methods in Natural Resource Damage
Assessment, Paper #2. Prepared for U.S. Department of Commerce, NOAA, Damage
Assessment and Restoration Program.

Kirchhoff, S., E.G. Colby, and J.T. LaFrance. 1997. "Evaluating the Performance of Benefit
Transfer: An Empirical Inquiry." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 33(1):
75-93.

Krupnick, A.J.  1993. "Benefits Transfers and Valuation of Environmental  Improvements."
Resources.

Loomis, J.B. 1993. Integrated Public Lands Management: Principles and Applications to
National Forests, Parks, Wildlife Refuges, and BLMLand. New York, New York: Columbia
University Press.

Loomis, J.B. 1992. "The Evolution of a More Rigorous Approach to Benefit Transfer: Benefit
Function Transfer."  Water Resources Research.  28(3): 701-705.

Loomis, J., A. Gonzales-Caban, and R. Gregory.  1994. "Do Reminders of Substitutes and
Budget Constraints Influence Contingent Valuation Estimates?" Land Economics. 70(4): 499-
506.

Mackenzie, J. 1992.  "Evaluating Recreation Trip Attributes and Travel Time via Conjoint
Analysis." Journal of 'Leisure Research 24(2): 171-184. National Recreation and Park
Association.

McConnell, K. and I.  Strand.  1981. "Measuring the Cost of Time in Recreation Demand
Analysis." American Journal of Agricultural Economics:  153-156.

Milon, J.W., C. Kiker, and D. Lee.  1997. "Ecosystem Management and the Florida Everglades:
The Role of Social Scientists." Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, July, 29(1): 99-
107.
                                                                              Page 174

-------
Mitchell, R.C. andR.T. Carson. 1989. Using Surveys to Value Public Goods:  The Contingent
Valuation Method.  Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future.

Mitchell, R.C. andR.T. Carson. 1986. The Use of Contingent Valuation Data for Benefit/Cost
Analysis in Water Pollution Control. Washington, D.C.:  Resources for the Future.

Mitchell, R.C. and R.T. Carson. 1984. An Experiment in Determining Willingness to Pay for
National Water Quality Improvements. Washington, D.C.:  Resources for the Future.

Morey, E.R.  "What Is Consumer Surplus per Day of Use, When Is it Content Independent of the
Number of Days of Use, and What Does it Tell Us about Consumer's  Surplus?" Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management 26: 257-270.

Morgan, M.G. and M. Henri on.  1990.  Uncertainty: Dealing with Uncertainty in Quantitative
Risk and Policy Analysis.  Cambridge University Press.  New York, New York.

Musser, W.N.  1997. "Why Economists Should Talk to Scientists and What They Should Ask:
Discussion." Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, July, 29(1): 109-112.

Opaluch JJ.  and MJ. Mazzotta. 1992. "Fundamental Issues in Benefit Transfer and Natural
Resource Damage Assessment." in Benefits Transfer: Procedures, Problems, and Research
Needs.  Snowbird, UT: Workshop Proceedings, Association of Environmental and Resource
Economists.

Palmquist, R. 1991. "Hedonic Methods." in Braden, John B. and Charles D. Kolstad, eds.
1991. Measuring the Demand for Environmental Quality. North-Holland, Amsterdam: Elsevier
Science Publishers.
Palmquist, R.B., F.M. Fritz, and T. Vukina. 1997. "Hog Operations, Environmental Effects, and
Residential Property Values." Land Economics 73(1): 114-124.

Pearce, David W.  1998.  "Auditing the Earth." Environment. 40(2): 23-28.

Pearce, David W.  1993. Economic Values and the Natural World. The MIT Press,  Cambridge,
Massachusetts.

Pearce, D.W. and R.K. Turner. 1990. Economics of Natural Re sources and the Environment.
Maryland: The Johns Hopkins University Press.

Pimentel, D., C. Wilson, C. McCullum, R. Huang, P. Dwen, J. Flack, Q. Tran, T. Saltman, B.
Cliff.  1997.  "Economic and Environmental Benefits of Biodiversity." BioScience. 47(11):
747-757.

Principe, P.  1995.  "Ecological Benefits Assessment:  A Policy-Oriented Alternative to Regional
Ecological Risk Assessment." Human and Ecological Risk Assessment 1(4): 423-435.

Randall, A., B. Ives, and C. Eastman. 1974. "Bidding Games for Valuation of Aesthetic
Environmental Improvements." Journal of Environmental Economics 1:  132-149.

                                                                              Page 175

-------
Rowe, R.W. 1985. Valuing Marine Recreational Fishing on the Pacific Coast. La Jolla,
California:  National Marine Fisheries Service, Southwest Fisheries Center.

Scodari, P.  1992.  Wetland Protection Benefits. Draft Report.  Prepared for the Office of Policy,
Planning, and Evaluation, U.S. EPA. Grant No. CR-817553-01.

Smith, V.K. 1992. "On Separating Defensible Benefit Transfers from Smoke and Mirrors."
Water Resources Research 28: 685-694.

Smith, V. K. 1989 "Taking Stock of Progress with Travel Cost Recreation Demand Methods:
Theory and Implementation."  Marine Resource Economics 6: 279-310.

Tietenberg, T.  1992. Environmental and Natural Resource Economics. HarperCollins
Publisher.

U.S. EPA. 2000.  Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses. U.S. EPA, Office of the
Administrator.  EPA/240/R-00/003.  September.

U.S. EPA.  1997. A Conceptual Model for the Economic Valuation of Ecosystem
Damages Resulting from Ozone Exposure.  Draft Report. Prepared by Science Applications
International Corporation, for the U.S. EPA, Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards.

U.S. EPA.  1997. Discounting in Environmental Policy Evaluation, Draft Final Report,
Prepared by Frank Arnold, Fran  Sussman, and Leland Deck for the U.S. EPA, Office of Policy,
Planning, and Evaluation. April 1, 1997.

U.S. EPA.  1997. Evaluating  the Equity of Environmental Policy Options Based on the
Distribution of Economic Effects, Draft. Prepared  for U.S. EPA, Office of Policy, Planning, and
Evaluation. May 23, 1997.

U.S. EPA.  1997.  Technical Assistance on a Review and Evaluation of Procedures Used to
Study Issues of Uncertainty in the Conduct of Economic Cost-Benefit Research and Analysis,
Draft Report.  Prepared by Hagler Bailly Consulting, Incorporated for the U.S. EPA, Office of
Policy, Planning, and Evaluation. May 27, 1997.

U.S. EPA, Oceans and  Coastal Protection Division. 1995. Assessing the Economic Value of
Estuary Resources and Resource Services in Comprehensive Conservation and Management
Plan (CCMP) Planning and Implementation, A National Estuary Program Environmental
Valuation Handbook. Washington, D.C.: U.S. EPA.

U.S. EPA, RTI.  1983.  A Comparison of Alternative Approaches for Estimating Recreation and
Related Benefits of Water Quality Improvements, EPA Document 230-05-83-001 Under
Cooperative Agreement #68-01-5838. Washington D.C.: U.S. EPA.

Viscusi, W. K.  1993. "The Value of Risks to Life and  Health." Journal of Economic
Literature.  XXXI(4): 1912-1946.
                                                                              Page 176

-------
Whittington, D., et al.  1994.  The Economic Value of Improving the Environmental Quality of
Galveston Bay.  Galveston National Estuary Program. Publication GBNEP-3B.

Willig, R. 1976. "Consumer Surplus Without Apology." American Economic Review 66(4):
589-597.

Willis, K. and G. Garrod.  1991.  "An Individual Travel  Cost Method of Evaluating Forest
Recreation." Journal of'AgriculturalEconomics 42(1):  33-42.
                                                                               Page 177

-------