November 19, 1999

EPA-SAB-COUNCIL-ADV-00-003

Honorable Carol M. Browner
Administrator
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency
401 M Street, SW
Washington, DC 20460

       RE:    Final Advisory by the Advisory Council on Clean Air Compliance Analysis on the
              1999 Prospective Study of Costs and Benefits (1999) of Implementation of the
              Clean Air Act Amendments (CAAA)

Dear Ms. Browner:

       On October 1, 1999, the Advisory Council on Clean Air Compliance Analysis (Council)
held a public teleconference to review a draft Agency document, The Benefits and Costs of the
Clean Air Act, 1990 to 2010; EPA Report to Congress (U.S. EPA, Office of Air and Radiation
and Office of Policy, September 1999) and held a follow-up teleconference on October 15, 1999
to review an October draft of that same document. These two  closure meetings represented the
culmination of a multi-year series of review meetings during which the Council provided advice to
the Agency on the study design, methodologies, and intermediate results. The Council submits
this Advisory to complete its review responsibilities as defined in Section 812 of the CAAA. l
       The Council believes that The Benefits and Costs of the Clean Air Act, 1990 to 2010 is a
serious, careful study that, in general, employs sound methods and data. While we do not endorse
all details of the study, we believe that the study's conclusions are generally consistent with the
weight of available evidence. The Council also appreciates the Agency's responsiveness over the
many years of this study's development to advice conveyed by the Council and its technical
subcommittees. While  the Project Team has not followed our advice in every instance, we believe
that they have done a remarkable job on an extremely difficult project.
       1 Specifically, subsection (g) of CAA §312 (as amended by §812 of the amendments) states:
"(g) The Council shall — (1) review the data to be used for any analysis required under this section and
make recommendations to the Administrator on the use of such data, (2) review the methodology used
to analyze such data and make recommendations to the Administrator on the use of such methodology;
and (3) prior to issuance of a report required under subsection (d) or (e), review the findings of such
report, and make recommendations to the Administrator concerning the validity and utility of such
findings."

-------
       We would, however, like to bring to your attention two major issues that arose in our
review of the study. These pertain to the study's measurement of costs and representation of
uncertainty regarding costs.  Following our discussion of these points, we present suggestions to
improve future Prospective Studies. Because of their importance, we would like to highlight
these suggestions here:

       a)     We believe that benefits and costs must be disaggregated by individual provision of
              the Clean Air Act if benefit-cost analysis is to be useful in informing regulation.

       b)     Future studies must attempt to quantify uncertainties about regulatory costs, as
              well as uncertainties about the benefits of regulations.  Failure to quantify cost
              uncertainties may give the impression that costs  cannot exceed point estimates.

       c)     Cost estimates should include tax-interaction effects; i.e., they should reflect the
              fact that environmental regulations may exacerbate the disincentive effects of the
              personal  and corporate income taxes.  This may  raise cost  estimates considerably.

       d)     The Agency should revise its estimates of the Value of a Statistical Life.

       e)     The impact of air quality regulations should be stated  in terms of a Net Cost per
              Life Saved and a Net Cost per Life-year  Saved to facilitate comparisons with other
              health and safety regulations.

       f)      Attempts should be made to increase the set of ecosystem  benefits valued and to
              improve  estimates of the exposure and effects of air toxics.

1.     Comments  on the Drafts Provided for Council Review

       a)     The Relationship between Direct and Social Costs of Compliance. Social cost is
              the type of cost that is most relevant to the evaluation of the 1990 Clean Air Act.
              However, the draft Prospective Study relies primarily  on estimates of the "direct"
              compliance costs for affected industries or pollution sources.  The reliance on
              direct costs is understandable, since  it is more difficult to assess the social costs.
              At the same time, it is important to articulate  clearly and without bias the
              relationship between direct and social  costs.

              The Council believes that the study's discussion of this issue lacks balance and is
              prone to  misinterpretation.  The study describes  in detail two factors that might
              cause direct costs to overstate true social costs (absence of attention to producer
              and consumer responses, and the assumption of a static technology). The October
              review draft contained a discussion of the tax-interaction effect, which can cause
              direct costs to understate social costs, possibly by a very large amount. In the
              Council's view, this effect merited discussion in the text and should not be

-------
       relegated to a footnote.  There is now a substantial body of published theoretical
       and empirical research that indicates that, under typical conditions, tax-interactions
       can cause social costs to exceed direct costs by at least 25 percent, and in some
       cases by 100 percent or more. Table 3-3 further contributes to potential
       misinterpretation.  It explicitly mentions a factor that would cause direct cost to
       overstate social cost (lack of attention to producer and consumer responses) but
       fails to mention explicitly the factor (tax interactions) that works in the opposite
       direction. By minimizing attention to the tax-interaction effect, the study gives
       readers the erroneous impression that the EPA's use of direct costs is likely to
       overstate social costs.

       Tax interactions occur when environmental regulations exacerbate the distortions
       in labor and capital markets caused by prior income, profit, or sales taxes.  These
       interactions may result from any regulations that raise production costs and
       thereby lower the real purchasing power stemming from given real wages.  Even
       "small" regulations can produce significant tax-interaction effects.  The
       Prospective Study fails to indicate the general relevance of these effects. The
       study states that general equilibrium  effects are important where the regulatory
       action is known to have an impact on many sectors of the US economy.  Although
       this statement is technically correct, it allows for the impression that such general
       equilibrium effects are unusual. It fails to point out the key finding from the
       tax-interaction literature: namely, that all regulatory actions have impacts on other
       sectors (particularly labor and capital markets) and that these general equilibrium
       impacts,  under typical conditions, raise social costs substantially relative to direct
       costs.

       In sum, the Council would urge the EPA to give more attention to the tax-
       interaction effect in order to achieve a more balanced and straightforward
       presentation of the relationship between direct costs and overall social cost.  This
       is necessary to avoid giving the false impression  that direct costs are likely to
       overstate social cost.

b)     Characterization of Uncertainty with Respect to Cost Estimates.  The main results
       of the first Prospective Study are summarized in  a table of costs and benefits that
       appears both in the Executive Summary and in Chapter 8. Uncertainties about the
       benefits of the CAAA are nicely illustrated by a lower bound and an upper bound
       (90% confidence interval). In contrast, the cost of this environmental protection is
       represented only by a central estimate. (Cost uncertainties are discussed via
       sensitivity analyses in other tables, but these uncertainties are not combined into an
       overall set of bounds on the central cost estimate.)

       Thus the benefit-cost ratios in that main summary table vary only with
       uncertainties about benefits. These ratios would  vary even more if they

-------
              incorporated some uncertainty about costs. Since costs are indeed uncertain, the
              table implicitly understates the true degree of uncertainty about the net benefits of
              the CAAA.

              Even rough representations of uncertainty about these costs would be better than
              the current implication that costs are certain. One possibility would be to assume a
              uniform distribution about each element of cost, ranging from 50% to 150% of the
              central estimate.  A second possibility is to show an additional row of benefit-cost
              ratios where the costs have been multiplied by 1.3 to account for the
              tax-interaction effect. A third possibility is suggested by reference to the fact that
              the Retrospective Study produced a central estimate of direct cost equal to $523
              billion, while the modeling approach provided welfare effects between $493 billion
              and $621 billion.  Since these bounds are 6% below and  19% above the central
              estimate, the same percentage bounds could be applied to the central estimate of
              costs in the Prospective Study. True bounds on costs in the Prospective Study
              would be preferred, but one of these rough estimates of bounds is better than using
              no bounds at all.

2.     Suggestions to Improve Future Prospective Studies

       a)     Disaggregate Benefits and Costs by Title or Provision. The Council reiterates its
              strong recommendation for presenting the benefits as well  as the costs of the
              CAAA by title and, preferably, by provision, in future studies. Without this level
              of disaggregation, the study cannot be used directly to identify how the CAAA
              might be improved in the future.  The Council recognizes that a thorough
              disaggregation analysis was not feasible for the current study since resources were
              not available for exercising several air quality models to  create the needed data
              base for the analysis.  Future studies should not be limited in this regard since more
              universal and versatile platforms for air quality modeling, such as Models-3, are
              expected to be available. With careful design, using such a system, a small number
              of additional comprehensive modeling simulations can provide the information
              needed for a thorough bottom-up assessment of the CAAA benefits by  individual
              title and even by  some provisions. If, in the design phase of the next prospective
              study, it becomes apparent that resources cannot be allocated for these analyses,
              then an alternative design strategy combining use of top-down or screening model
              approaches combined with carefully selected essential comprehensive model
              simulations should be pursued.

       b)     Characterize Uncertainty about Costs.  The costs imposed by air pollution
              regulations are highly uncertain.  For example, the costs  of sulfur dioxide
              abatement under the 1990 Clean Air Act have turned out to be a fraction of what
              was estimated in 1990.  Unfortunately, uncertainty can lead to higher as well as
              lower costs.

-------
              EPA has relied on engineering estimates of abatement costs. Even if these
              estimates were accurate estimates of the cost of equipment and operating costs,
              they would understate social costs because of tax-interaction and other effects.
              EPA needs to discuss and to quantify the following sources of uncertainty:

              (1)    Uncertainty in the engineering cost estimates.

              (2)    Costs in addition to the engineering estimates, such as tax-interactions.

              (3)    Technical change due to the technology forcing that lowers costs.

              (4)    Changes in the wage rate or prices of materials due to the changes in
                     demand.

       c)     Include Tax-Interaction Effects in Future Cost Estimates.  One of the most
              important insights to emerge in Environmental Economics in the past 25 years is
              that regulations, by exacerbating existing distortions in the economy, can have
              social costs considerably in excess of direct compliance costs.  An environmental
              regulation that raises the price of purchased goods and lowers the real wage will
              tend to, other things equal, cause a substitution of leisure for labor.  This
              compounds the deadweight loss of the tax system, which, by driving a wedge
              between the gross and net of tax wages, causes individuals to substitute leisure for
              labor.  This tax-interaction effect can, in some cases, double the costs of a
              regulation  (Goulder et al. 1999, Parry et al. 1999).2

              It is important for tax-interaction effects to be included in future Prospective
              Studies for two reasons.  First, these costs are real.  They represent real losses in
              output, and they occur even for small regulations. Second, the tax-interaction
              effect can at least to some degree be offset if the environmental program raises
              revenues, which are used to reduce the rates of other, distorting taxes.  This
              implies that the costs  of a program will depend on how a standard is achieved,
              which has implications for the choice of regulatory approach. For example, a
              permit market will have lower social costs if permits are auctioned and revenues
              recycled than if permits are given away (Goulder et al. 1997; Parry 1997).3
       2 Goulder, Lawrence H., Ian W. H. Parry, Roberton C. Williams III, and Dallas Burtraw, 1999. "The Cost-
Effectiveness of Alternative Instruments for Environmental Protection in a Second-Best Setting," Journal of Public
Economics 72(3):329-360; and Pany, Ian, W. H., R. C. Williams III, and L. H. Goulder, 1999. "When Can Caibon
Abatement Policies Increase Welfare? The Fundamental Role of Distorted Factor Markets," Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management 37:52-84.

       3 Goulder, Lawrence H., Parry, Ian W. H., and Dallas Burtraw, "Revenue-Raising vs. Other Approaches to
Environmental Protection: The Critical Significance of Pre-Existing Tax Distortions," RAND Journal of

-------
       d)     Revise Mortality Risk Estimates. The Council is uncomfortable with the Agency's
              use of $4.8 million (1990 U.S. dollars) for the Value of a Statistical Life (VSL)
              and $293,000 for the Value of a Statistical Life-year (VSLY) to value mortality
              risk reductions from reduced air pollution. We question the appropriateness of the
              $4.8 million VSL even as a measure of prime-aged individuals' willingness to pay
              (WTP) for risk reductions, and we question the application of a WTP estimate for
              prime-aged individuals to a population of older individuals and people who are in
              poor health. Time limitations did not permit a thorough treatment of this issue
              prior to completing the first Prospective Study; hence we recommended that the
              Project Team use the $4.8 million figure.  For future studies, however, we
              recommend that the Agency revisit the literature on the value of mortality risk
              reductions. The following points should be kept in mind when examining this
              literature:

              (1)    It is WTP for risk reductions that is the appropriate concept when valuing
                     the mortality benefits of environmental regulations. The costs of
                     environmental regulations are spread broadly over many individuals who,
                     indeed, are paying for the resulting risk reductions.

              (2)    Labor market studies measure willingness to accept (WTA) compensation
                     for increased risk of death.  This is likely to exceed what people will pay
                     (WTP) for the same risk reductions.

              (3)    Averting behavior and consumer product safety studies, which are omitted
                     from the current list of 26 studies, do measure WTP.  These studies should
                     be considered in the review.

              (4)    In reviewing studies the population whose preferences are measured should
                     be noted, as should the magnitude of the risk reduction valued. Studies
                     should be identified that measure WTP for risk reductions among the
                     populations that benefit from air quality regulation, especially older people,
                     and that value risk reductions of the same magnitude as those in future
                     Prospective Studies.

              (5)    There should be well-defined criteria  for selecting studies, which are clearly
                     stated and consistently applied. For example, compensating wage studies
                     should adequately control for inter-industry wage differentials; contingent
                     valuation studies should test for sensitivity to scope.
Economics, Winter 1997; and Parry, Ian W. H., "Environmental Taxes and Quotas in the Presence of
Distorting Taxes in Factor Markets," Resource and Energy Economics, Winter 1997,19:203-20.

-------
e)     Present Cost-Effectiveness Results. Improvements in human health remain a major
       motivation behind air quality regulation and account for over 90% of the quantified
       benefits from Titles I-IV of the 1990 CAAA.  Reductions in premature mortality,
       in turn, account for over 90% of these health benefits. Because mortality risk
       reductions are such a large component of the benefits from air quality regulation,
       the Council urges the Agency to express the outcomes of the CAAA in terms of:
       (1) Net Cost per Life Saved, and (2) Net Cost per Life-Year Saved.  These are
       calculated by subtracting the value of non-mortality benefits from costs and
       dividing the result by: (1) the number of statistical lives saved, and (2) the number
       of statistical life-years saved.
       By taking this approach the Agency would: (1) provide a measure of program
       effectiveness that avoids the use of flawed measures of VSL and VSLY and, more
       generally, avoids the controversies surrounding the valuation of mortality risk
       change; (2) be in line with standard practice in the public health community, where
       different programs are routinely compared using cost-effectiveness analysis; and
       (3) facilitate comparisons of the cost effectiveness of various health and safety
       programs with health-based environmental regulations. The Council feels such
       comparisons are necessary for improving public decisions about the allocation of
       society's scarce  resources among competing ends.

f)     Increase Set of Ecosystem Benefits Valued. The current Prospective Study has
       made important advances in identifying  ecosystem services that can be linked to air
       pollution, and in trying  to value these endpoints.  For the purposes of valuation, it
       is convenient to categorize the impact of pollution on ecosystems as follows:  (1)
       impacts that occur through markets (e.g., impacts of pollution on commercial
       timber stands or fish populations); (2) impacts that affect recreation (e.g., damage
       to National Parks from  air pollution or to recreational fishing from acid rain); (3)
       impacts on ecosystems  for which people have well-defined non-use values (e.g.,
       damage to forest canopy, the value of reduced fish populations to non-anglers);
       and (4) other impacts on ecosystem functions and services, not otherwise
       classified, for example water and nutrient recycling, maintenance of biodiversity,
       climate stabilization. These indirect and more subtle effects may not be well
       understood or even perceived by people; yet they may have important impacts on
       human well being.

       Techniques for valuing  the first 3 categories of benefits are well-established, but
       the set of applied studies is sparse. The  Agency might consider funding new
       studies, after determining which categories of benefits are likely to have the largest
       impact on regulatory decisions. When commissioning studies to measure non-use
       values, care should be taken in defining: (1) the geographical scope of what is to
       be valued (for example, are people asked only for non-use values in their state?);
       (2) the nature of substitutes (i.e., conditions at other locations); and (3) how many
       endpoints to value at the same time.  For example, in regard to this last point, if a

-------
              regulation to reduce nitrogen oxides (NOx) affects forests through ozone and fish
              population through acid rain, people should be asked to value the entire package
              of ecosystem benefits brought about by NOx reduction. Adding up WTP values
              from individual studies might overstate the value of the NOx reduction program if
              there are important substitution effects across ecosystem services.

              A problem for policy analysis is that the endpoints that affect markets or for which
              people have well-defined use (recreation) and non-use values (e.g., damages to
              forests, fish and wildlife populations) do not capture the totality of ecosystem
              damages associated with pollution control decisions.  In particular, they do not
              capture ecosystem functions and services  such as nutrient recycling and habitat
              provision.  Nor do they capture the more subtle changes in ecosystem functioning
              that may to lead to non-marginal changes in ecosystem performance.  Before these
              changes can be valued, however, it is essential that ecologists characterize the
              ecosystem outcomes (or indicators) that are important to ecosystem functioning
              and then relate these outcomes (or indicators) to particular activities or pollutants.
              This information is an essential foundation for economic valuation.

       g)     Estimate Exposure  and Effects of Air Toxics. The Retrospective Study and the
              first Prospective Study do not contain any quantitative benefit-cost analyses of
              Toxic Air Pollutants (TAP). As the Council's Health and Ecological Effects
              Subcommittee (HEES) has stated,4 the Agency does not currently have analytical
              methodologies available to establish population exposure estimates, or to define
              realistic risk estimates for the general population. The HEES, with approval by the
              full Council, suggested an approach to identifying the research and methodological
              developments needed to overcome these deficiencies.  The effort requires
              coordination with the SAB Executive Committee, various SAB Committees, the
              Office of Research and Development and  Office of Air Quality Planning and
              Standards. Implementation of the plan of action outlined for the Agency will begin
              a process that can lead to quantitative estimates of health, and possibly ecological
              benefits for the next Prospective Study.

3.     Conclusion

       The purpose of conducting benefit-cost analyses is to improve the efficiency of regulation.
The suggestions we have made in this Advisory are designed to help achieve this goal.  Increasing
the accuracy of benefit-cost analyses will entail measuring certain categories of benefits (e.g.,
certain ecological benefits, benefits of reduced exposure  to hazardous air pollutants) and costs
(tax-interaction effects) not included in the current Prospective Study. It will also entail refining
estimates of the value of mortality benefits, which continue to dominate the monetized benefits of
       4 See HEES Letter Advisories, "The Clean Air Act Amendments (CAAA) Section 812 Prospective Study of Costs and Benefits (1999):
Advisory by the Health and Ecological Effects Subcommittee on Initial Assessments of Health and Ecological Effects, Part 1", EPA-SAB-COUNCIL-
ADV-99-012 and "Part 2", EPA-SAB-COUNCIL-ADV-00-001.

-------
improved air quality. Of all the suggestions made above, however, we believe that disaggregating
the benefits and costs of individual provisions of the CAA is, perhaps, the most important. If our
recommendation to provide more disaggregated benefit-cost estimates can be implemented, the
specific programs which have the highest potential payoff to society can be more readily
identified. We strongly encourage the Agency to make the research investment and analytical
commitments required to ensure this objective is met in the next prospective study.

-------
       We thank the Agency for the opportunity to review the first Prospective Study and to
make recommendations to improve the methods and data to be used in future prospective studies.
We look forward to your response to this Advisory.
                           Sincerely,
                                  /signed/
                           Dr. Maureen L. Cropper, Chair
                           Advisory Council on Clean Air Compliance Analysis
                           Science Advisory Board
                                           10

-------
                                       NOTICE
       This report has been written as part of the activities of the Science Advisory Board, a
public advisory group providing extramural scientific information and advice to the Administrator
and other officials of the Environmental Protection Agency.  The Board is structured to provide
balanced, expert assessment of scientific matters related to problems facing the Agency. This
report has not been reviewed for approval by the Agency and, hence, the contents of this report
do not necessarily represent the views and policies of the Environmental Protection Agency, nor
of other agencies in the Executive Branch of the Federal government, nor does mention of trade
names or commercial products constitute a recommendation for use.
Distribution and Availability: This Science Advisory Board report is provided to the EPA
Administrator, senior Agency management, appropriate program staff, interested members of the
public, and is posted on the SAB website (www.epa.gov/sab). Information on its availability is

-------
also provided in the SAB's monthly newsletter (Happenings at the Science Advisory Board).
Additional copies and further information are available from the SAB Staff.

-------
                 U.S. ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY
                        SCIENCE ADVISORY BOARD (SAB)
           ADVISORY COUNCIL ON CLEAN AIR COMPLIANCE ANALYSIS

CHAIR
Dr. Maureen L. Cropper, The World Bank, Washington, DC

MEMBERS
Dr. Gardner M. Brown, University of Washington, Seattle, WA

Dr. Trudy Ann Cameron, University of California, Los Angeles, CA.

Dr. Don Fullerton, University of Texas, Austin, TX

Dr. Lawrence H. Goulder, Stanford University, Stanford, CA

Dr. Jane V. Hall, California State University, Fullerton, CA

Dr. Charles Kolstad, University of California, Santa Barbara, CA

Dr. Paul Lioy, Robert Wood Johnson School of Medicine, Piscataway, NJ

Dr. Paulette Middleton, RAND Center for Science & Policy, Boulder, CO

CONSULTANTS
Dr. A. Myrick Freeman, Bowdoin College, ME

Dr. Alan J. Krupnick, Resources for the Future, Washington, DC

SCIENCE ADVISORY BOARD STAFF
Dr. Angela Nugent, Designated Federal Officer, Science Advisory Board, U.S. Environmental
      Protection Agency, Washington, DC

Mrs. Diana L. Pozun, Management Assistant, Science Advisory Board, U.S. Environmental
      Protection Agency, Washington, DC

-------