REGULATORY IMPACT ANALYSIS FOR THE PROPOSED
REVISIONS TO THE EMISSION GUIDELINES FOR EXISTING
SOURCES AND SUPPLEMENTAL PROPOSED NEW SOURCE
PERFORMANCE STANDARDS IN THE MUNICIPAL SOLID
WASTE LANDFILLS SECTOR

-------
This page intentionally left blank.

-------
                                                        EPA-452/R-15-008
                                                             August 2015
Regulatory Impact Analysis for the Proposed Revisions to the Emission Guidelines
    for Existing Sources and Supplemental Proposed New Source Performance
            Standards in the Municipal Solid Waste Landfills Sector
                   U.S. Environmental Protection Agency
                        Office of Air and Radiation
                 Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards
                 Health and Environmental Impacts Division
                     Research Triangle Park, NC 27711

-------
                             CONTACT INFORMATION
This document has been prepared by staff from the Office of Air and Radiation, U.S.
Environmental Protection Agency. Questions related to this document should be addressed to
Charles Fulcher, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Office of Air and Radiation, Office of
Air Quality Planning and Standards, C439-02, Research Triangle Park, North Carolina 27711
(email: fulcher.charles@epa.gov).
                              ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
       In addition to EPA staff from the Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards and the
Office of Atmospheric Programs with the U.S. EPA Office of Air and Radiation, Eastern
Research Group, Inc. (ERG) contributed data and analysis to this document.
                                          11

-------
                                   TABLE OF CONTENTS


TABLE OF CONTENTS	m

LIST OF TABLES	vi

LIST OF FIGURES	vm

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY	ES-1

  ES.l BACKGROUND	ES-1
  ES.2 RESULTS FOR PROPOSED REVISIONS TO EMISSION GUIDELINES	ES-1
  ES. 3 RESULTS FOR SUPPLEMENTAL PROPOSED NEW SOURCE PERFORMANCE STANDARDS	ES-3
  ES.3 ORGANIZATION OF THIS REPORT	ES-5

1    INTRODUCTION	1-1

  1.1  BACKGROUND	1-1
  1.2  STATEMENT OF NEED FOR POLICY ACTION	1-3
     1.2.1   Protection of Human Health and the Environment	1-3
     1.2.2   Need for Regulatory Intervention Because of Market Failure	1-4
       1.2.2.1    Air Pollution as an Externality	1-4
  1.3  ORGANIZATION OF THIS REPORT	1-4
  1.4  REFERENCES	1-5

2    INDUSTRY PROFILE	2-1

  2.1  INTRODUCTION	2-1
  2.2  WASTE STREAM BACKGROUND	2-3
     2.2.1   Municipal Waste	2-3
       2.2.1.1    Generation of MS W	2-3
       2.2.1.2    Landfills Covered Under the EG	2-4
       2.2.1.3    Trends in Per Capita Waste Sent to Landfills	2-4
       2.2.1.4    Composition of MS W Sent to Landfills	2-5
     2.2.2   Consolidation of Waste Streams	2-7
  2.3  DISPOSAL FACILITY BACKGROUND	2-8
     2.3.1   Technical Background on Landfills as a Source Category	2-8
       2.3.1.1    Landfill Siting and Permitting	2-8
       2.3.1.2    Landfill Operations	2-9
       2.3.1.3    Landfill Closure	2-10
       2.3.1.4    Management of Liquids	2-10
     2.3.2   Ownership and Characteristics of Landfills	2-11
  2.4  COSTS AND REVENUE STREAMS FOR LANDFILLS	2-15
     2.4.1   Major Cost Components for Landfills	2-15
     2.4.2   Landfill Revenue Sources	2-18
  2.5  AIR POLLUTANT EMISSIONS FROM LANDFILLS	2-21
     2.5.1   NMOCinLFG	2-21
     2.5.2   Methane in LFG	2-22
     2.5.3   Criteria Pollutants from Combustion of LFG	2-23
  2.6  TECHNIQUES FOR CONTROLLING EMISSIONS FROM LANDFILLS	2-24
     2.6.1   Introduction	2-24
     2.6.2   Gas Collection Systems	2-24
     2.6.3   Destruction	2-26
     2.6.4   Utilization	2-28
       2.6.4.1    Technologies	2-28
       2.6.4.2    Revenues and Incentives	2-33
  2.7  INTEGRATED WASTE MANAGEMENT STRATEGIES	2-36
     2.7.1   Introduction	2-36
                                               ill

-------
     2.7.2    Organics Management	2-37
       2.7.2.1    Trends	2-38
       2.7.2.2    Benefits	2-40
       2.7.2.3    Barriers	2-40
  2.8  REFERENCES	2-42

3    REGULATORY PROGRAM COSTS AND EMISSIONS REDUCTIONS	3-1

  3.1  INTRODUCTION	3-1
  3.2  GENERAL ASSUMPTIONS AND PROCEDURES	3-1
  3.3  EMISSIONS ANALYSIS	3-3
  3.4  ENGINEERING AND ADMINISTRATIVE COST ANALYSIS	3-4
  3.5  REGULATORY BASELINE AND OPTIONS	3-7
  3.6  ALTERNATIVE YEARS OF ANALYSIS	3-12

4    BENEFITS OF EMISSIONS REDUCTIONS	4-1

  4.1  INTRODUCTION	4-1
  4.2  METHANE (CH4)	4-4
     4.2.1    Methane climate effects and valuation	4-4
     4.2.2    Methane as an ozone precursor	4-16
     4.2.3    Combined climate and ozone effects of methane	4-17
  4.3  VOC AS A PM2.5 PRECURSOR	4-18
     4.3.1    PM2 5 health effects and valuation	4-19
     4.3.2    Visibility Effects	4-23
  4.4  VOC AS AN OZONE PRECURSOR	4-23
     4.4.1    Ozone health effects and valuation	4-24
     4.4.2    Ozone vegetation effects	4-25
     4.4.3    Ozone climate effects	4-25
  4.5  HAZARDOUS AIR POLLUTANT (HAP) BENEFITS	4-26
     4.5.1    Benzene	4-31
     4.5.2    Ethylbenzene	4-32
     4.5.3    Toluene	4-33
     4.5.4    Vinyl Chloride	4-34
     4.5.5    Other Air Toxics	4-35
  4.6  ALTERNATIVE YEARS OF ANALYSIS	4-35
  4.7  REFERENCES	4-36

5    ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS AND DISTRIBUTIONAL ASSESSMENTS	5-1

  5.1  INTRODUCTION	5-1
  5.2  ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS	5-1
  5.3  EMPLOYMENT IMPACTS	5-2
     5.3.1    Background on the Regulated Industry	5-3
     5.3.2    Employment Impacts of Environmental Regulation	5-6
     5.3.3    Conclusion	5-11
  5.4  SMALL BUSINESS IMPACTS ANALYSIS	5-12
  5.5  REFERENCES	5-13

6    COMPARISON OF BENEFITS AND COST	6-1

  6.1  INTRODUCTION	6-1
  6.2  NET BENEFITS OF THE PROPOSED STANDARDS	6-1
  6.3  NET BENEFITS OF THE ALTERNATE STANDARDS	6-2

7    SUPPLEMENTAL NSPS PROPOSAL	7-1

  7.1  INTRODUCTION	7-1
  7.2  REGULATORY BASELINE AND OPTIONS	7-2
  7.3  BENEFITS	7-8
                                             IV

-------
  7.4   ECONOMIC IMPACTS	7-11
    7.4.1   Economic Impact Analysis	7-11
    7.4.2   Employment Impacts	7-11
    7.4.3   Small Business Impacts Analysis	7-11
  7.5   COMPARISON OF BENEFITS AND COSTS	7-13
  7.6   NET BENEFITS OF THE PROPOSED STANDARDS	7-14
  7.7   NET BENEFITS OF THE ALTERNATE STANDARDS	7-15
  7.8   ALTERNATIVE YEARS OF ANALYSIS	7-18

8   STATUTORY AND EXECUTIVE ORDER REVIEWS	8-1

  8.1   EXECUTIVE ORDER 12866, REGULATORY PLANNING AND REVIEW AND EXECUTIVE ORDER 13563,
  IMPROVING REGULATION AND REGULATORY REVIEW	8-1
  8.2   PAPERWORK REDUCTION ACT	8-2
  8.3   REGULATORY FLEXIBILITY ACT	8-4
  8.4   UNFUNDED MANDATES REFORM ACT	8-5
  8.5   EXECUTIVE ORDER 13132: FEDERALISM	8-7
  8.6   EXECUTIVE ORDER 13175: CONSULTATION AND COORDINATION WITH INDIAN TRIBAL GOVERNMENTS ... 8-8
  8.7   EXECUTIVE ORDER 13045: PROTECTION OF CHILDREN FROM ENVIRONMENTAL HEALTH RISKS AND SAFETY
  RISKS	8-9
  8.8   EXECUTIVE ORDER 13211: ACTIONS CONCERNING REGULATIONS THAT SIGNIFICANTLY AFFECT ENERGY
  SUPPLY, DISTRIBUTION, OR USE	8-10
  8.9   NATIONAL TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER AND ADVANCEMENT ACT	8-10
  8.10 EXECUTIVE ORDER 12898: ENVIRONMENTAL JUSTICE	8-11

-------
                                         LIST OF TABLES
Table ES-1  Summary of the Monetized Benefits, Costs, and Net Benefits for the Proposed Emission Guidelines for
Existing MSW Landfills in 2025 (2012$)	ES-3
Table ES-2  Summary of the Monetized Benefits, Costs, and Net Benefits for the Supplemental Proposed New
Source Performance Standards for MSW Landfills in 2025 (2012$)	ES-5
Table 2-1  Generation and Discards of MSW, 1960 to 2012 (in pounds per person per day) 	2-5
Table 2-2  Materials Discarded3 In the MSW Stream, 1960 to 2012 (in thousands of tons)	2-7
Table 2-3  Top 5 Waste Management Companies That Owned or Operated MSW Landfills in the United States in
2013a	2-14
Table 2-4  Typical Costs Per Acre for Components of Landfill Construction (Duffy, 2005a)	2-16
Table 2-5  Average Regional and National Per-Ton Tip Fees (Rounded): 1995-2011	2-19
Table 2-6  Average LFG Power Production Technology Costs	2-29
Table 2-7  Average LFG Direct-use Project Components Costs	2-31
Table 2-8  Waste Management of Organics in the United States	2-39
Table 3-1  Number of Affected Landfills in 2025 under the Baseline and Alternative Options	3-8
Table 3-2  Estimated Annual Average Emissions Reductions in 2025 for the Baseline and Alternative Options... 3-9
Table 3-3  Estimated Engineering Compliance Costs in 2025 for Baseline and Alternative Options (7% Discount
Rate)	3-10
Table 3-4  Estimated Engineering Compliance Costs in 2025 for Baseline and Alternative Options (3% Discount
Rate)	3-11
Table 3-5  Estimated Cost-effectiveness in 2025 for the Baseline and Alternative Options (7% Discount Rate).. 3-12
Table 3-6  Estimated Annual Average Emissions Reductions in 2020 for the Baseline and Alternative Options. 3-13
Table 3-7  Estimated Engineering Compliance Costs in 2020 for Baseline and Alternative Options (7% Discount
Rate)	3-13
Table 3-8  Estimated Annual Average Emissions Reductions in 2030 for the Baseline and Alternative Options. 3-14
Table 3-9  Estimated Engineering Compliance Costs in 2030 for Baseline and Alternative Options (7% Discount
Rate)	3-14
Table 3-10 Estimated Annual Average  Emissions Reductions in 2040 for the Baseline and Alternative Options 3-15
Table 3-11 Estimated Engineering Compliance Costs in 2040 for Baseline and Alternative Options (7% Discount
Rate)	3-15
Table 4-1  Climate and Human Health Effects of Emission Reductions in this Rule	4-2
Table 4-2  Social Cost of CH4, 2012 - 2050a [in 2012$ per metric ton] (Source: Marten et al., 2014b)	4-12
Table 4-3  Estimated Global Benefits of CH4 Reductions in 2025* (in millions, 2012$)	4-14
Table 4-4  Estimated Global Benefits of Net CO2 Reductions in 2025* (in millions, 2012$)	4-15
Table 4-5  Monetized Benefits-per-Ton Estimates for VOC based on Previous Modeling in 2015 (2012$)	4-22
Table 4-6  Estimated Global Benefits of CH4 Reductions in 2020* (in millions, 2012$)	4-35
Table 4-7  Estimated Global Benefits of CH4 Reductions in 2030* (in millions, 2012$)	4-36
Table 4-8  Estimated Global Benefits of CH4 Reductions in 2040* (in millions, 2012$)	4-36
Table 6-1  Summary of the Monetized Benefits, Costs, and Net Benefits for the Proposed Emission Guidelines
Option 2.5/34 in 2025 (2012$)	6-2
Table 6-2  Summary of the Monetized Benefits, Costs, and Net Benefits for the Alternative Emission Guidelines
Option 2.5/40 in 2025 (2012$)	6-3
Table 6-3  Summary of the Monetized Benefits, Costs, and Net Benefits for the Alternative Emission Guidelines
Option 2.0/34 in 2025 (2012$)	6-4
Table 7-1  Number of Affected Landfills in 2025 under the Baseline and Alternative Options	7-4
Table 7-2  Estimated Annual Average Emissions Reductions in 2025 for the Baseline and Alternative Options ... 7-5
Table 7-3  Estimated Engineering Compliance Costs in 2025 for Baseline and Alternative Options (7% Discount
Rate)	7-6
Table 7-4  Estimated Engineering Compliance Costs in 2025 for Baseline and Alternative Options (3% Discount
Rate)	7-7
Table 7-5  Estimated Cost-effectiveness in 2025 for the Baseline and Alternative Options (7% Discount Rate).... 7-8
Table 7-6  Estimated Global Benefits of CH4 Reductions in 2025* (in millions, 2012$)	7-10
Table 7-7  Estimated Global Disbenefits of Net CO2 Increases in 2025* (in millions, 2012$)	7-10
Table 7-8  Small Business Impact Screening Assessment Results (Reporters and Controllers)	7-13
                                                  VI

-------
Table 7-9  Summary of the Monetized Benefits, Costs, and Net Benefits for the Proposed NSPS Option 2.5/34 in
2025(2012$)	7-15
Table 7-10  Summary of the Monetized Benefits, Costs, and Net Benefits for the Alternative NSPS Option 2.5/40 in
2025(2012$)	7-17
Table 7-11  Summary of the Monetized Benefits, Costs, and Net Benefits for the Alternative NSPS Option 2.0/34 in
2025(2012$)	7-18
Table 7-12  Estimated Annual Average Emissions Reductions in 2020 for the Baseline and Alternative Options 7-19
Table 7-13  Estimated Engineering Compliance Costs in 2020 for Baseline and Alternative Options (7% Discount
Rate)	7-19
Table 7-14  Estimated Annual Average Emissions Reductions in 2030 for the Baseline and Alternative Options 7-20
Table 7-15  Estimated Engineering Compliance Costs in 2030 for Baseline and Alternative Options (7% Discount
Rate)	7-20
Table 7-16  Estimated Annual Average Emissions Reductions in 2040 for the Baseline and Alternative Options 7-21
Table 7-17  Estimated Engineering Compliance Costs in 2040 for Baseline and Alternative Options (7% Discount
Rate)	7-21
Table 7-18  Estimated Global Benefits of CH4 Reductions in 2020* (in millions, 2012$)	7-22
Table 7-19  Estimated Global Benefits of CH4 Reductions in 2030* (in millions, 2012$)	7-22
Table 7-20  Estimated Global Benefits of CH4 Reductions in 2040* (in millions, 2012$)	7-22
                                                  Vll

-------
                                       LIST OF FIGURES


Figure 2-1  Material Composition of the MSW Discard Stream, 2012                                     2-6
Figure 2-2  Landfill Cost Life Cycle                                                                 2-18
Figure 2-3  Typical LFG Generation Curve                                                           2-23
Figure 2-4  Vertical Well LFG Collection                                                            2-25
Figure 2-5  Horizontal Well LFG Collection                                                          2-25
Figure 4-1  Path from GHG Emissions to Monetized Damages (Source: Marten et al., 2014)                  4-9
Figure 4-2  2005 NATA Model Estimated Census Tract Carcinogenic Risk from HAP Exposure from Emissions of
All Outdoor Sources (inclusive of Residental Wood Heaters) based on the 2005 National Toxic Inventory.     4-28
Figure 4-3  2005 NATA Model Estimated Census Tract Noncancer Risk from HAP Exposure from Emissions of
All Outdoor Sources (inclusive of Residental Wood Heaters) based on the 2005 National Toxic Inventory      4-29
                                                Vlll

-------
                               EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

ES.l Background

       The U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) is proposing revisions to the Emission
Guidelines for existing Municipal Solid Waste Landfills. The EPA is not statutorily obligated to
conduct a review of the Emission Guidelines, but has the discretionary authority to do so when
circumstances indicate that this is appropriate. Based on changes in the landfills industry and
changes in size, ownership, and age of landfills since the Emission Guidelines were promulgated
in 1996, the EPA has concluded that it is appropriate to review the landfills Emission Guidelines
at this time. Based on our review, we are proposing to lower the annual NMOC emissions
threshold from 50 Mg/year to 34 Mg/year.

       In addition, the EPA is proposing Supplemental New Source Performance Standards for
new or modified Municipal Solid Waste Landfills. On July 17, 2014, the EPA proposed a new
NSPS subpart that retained the same design capacity size threshold of 2.5 million m3 or 2.5
million Mg, but presented several options for revising the NMOC emission rate at which a MSW
landfill must install controls. Since presenting these options, the EPA has updated its model that
estimates the emission reduction and cost impacts based on public comments and new data. As a
result of these data and model improvements, we are now proposing to lower the annual NMOC
emissions threshold from 50 Mg/year to 34 Mg/year.

ES.2 Results for Proposed Revisions to Emission Guidelines

       For the proposed revisions to the Emission Guidelines for existing MSW landfills, the
key results of the RIA follow and are summarized in Table ES-1:

Engineering Cost Analysis: To meet the proposed emission limits, a MSW landfill is expected
to install the least cost control for combusting the landfill gas. The control costs include the costs
to install and operate gas collection. For landfills where the least cost control option was an
engine, the costs also include installing and operate one or more reciprocating internal
combustion engines to convert the landfill gas into electricity. Revenue from electricity sales was
incorporated into the net control  costs using state-specific data on wholesale purchase prices. The
annualized costs also include testing and monitoring costs. For this proposal, which tightens the
emissions threshold, the EPA estimated the nationwide incremental annualized compliance cost
in 2025 to be  $46.8 million (2012$) using a 7% discount rate. Using a 3% discount rate, the
                                         ES-1

-------
nationwide incremental annualized compliance cost in 2025 is estimated to be $35 million
(2012$).

Emissions Analysis: In 2025, this proposal would achieve reductions of 2,770 Mg NMOC and
436,100 Mg methane (10.9 million Mg CCh-equivalents1) compared to the baseline. In addition,
the proposal is expected to result in the net reduction of 238,000 Mg CO2, due to reduced
demand for electricity from the grid as landfills generate electricity from landfill gas.2 These
pollutants are associated with substantial health, welfare and climate effects.

Benefits: The monetized benefits in this RIA include those from reducing 436,100 Mg methane,
which are valued using the social cost of methane (SC-CH/t), and the reductions in CO2, which
are valued using the social cost of carbon (SC-CCh). The EPA estimates that, in 2025, the
proposal will yield monetized climate benefits of $310 million (2012$) to approximately $1.7
billion (2012$)3; the mean SC-CH4 at the 3% discount rate results in an estimate of about $660
million (2012$) in 2025. The climate  benefits associated with the reduction of 238,000 Mg CO2
are estimated to be $12 million (2012$) in 2025. The benefits from reducing some air pollutants
have not been monetized in this analysis due to data, resource, and methodological limitations,
including reducing 2,770 Mg NMOC (including undetermined amounts of HAPs). We assessed
the benefits of these emission reductions qualitatively in this RIA.

Small Entity Analysis: The EPA certifies that the proposed Emission Guidelines will not have a
Significant Impact on a Substantial Number of Small Entities (SISNOSE) because the proposed
rule will not impose any requirements on small entities. Specifically, Emission Guidelines
established under CAA section 11 l(d) do not impose any requirements on regulated entities and,
thus, will not have a significant economic impact upon a substantial number of small entities.

Economic Impacts: Because of the relatively low net compliance cost of this proposal
compared to the overall size of the MSW landfill industry, as well as the lack of appropriate
economic parameters or models, the EPA is unable to estimate the impacts of the proposal on the
supply and demand for MSW landfill services. However, the EPA does not believe the proposal
will lead to changes in supply and demand for landfill services or waste disposal costs, tipping
fees, or the amount of waste disposed in landfills. Hence, the overall economic impact of the
proposal should be minimal on the affected industries and  their consumers.
1 A global warming potential of 25 is used to convert methane to CCh-equivalents.
2 The reduced demand for electricity from the grid more than offsets the additional energy demand required to
  operate the control system and the by-product emissions from the combustion of LFG.
3 The range of estimates reflects four SC-CH4 estimates: the mean across all models and scenarios using a 2.5
  percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount rate, and the 95th percentile of the pooled estimates from all models
  and scenarios using a 3% discount rate. See Section 4.2 for a complete discussion.


                                          ES-2

-------
Table ES-1   Summary of the Monetized Benefits, Costs, and Net Benefits for the Proposed
Emission Guidelines for Existing MSW Landfills in 2025 (2012$)

                                       3% Discount Rate           7% Discount Rate

 Total Monetized Benefits1                                 $670 million
 Total Costs2                               $35 million                  $47 million
 Net Benefits                               $640 million                 $620 million
 XT       ..  j „    c. ->            Hearth effects of PM2 5 and ozone exposure from 2,770 Mg
 Non-monetized Benefits3            XTA*/^/    j   j
                                  NMOC/yr reduced
                                  Health effects of HAP exposure from 2,770 Mg NMOC/yr
                                  reduced
                                  Visibility impairment
                                  Vegetation effects
 1 Monetized benefits include the climate-related benefits associated with the reduction of 436,100
 Mg/yr methane ($660 million, valued using the social cost of methane) and the net reduction of 238,000
 Mg/yr of CO2 ($12 million, valued using the social cost of carbon). The social cost of methane and
 social cost of carbon estimates are calculated with four different values of a one ton reduction (model
 average at 2.5 percent discount rate, 3 percent, and 5 percent; 95th percentile at 3 percent). For the
 purposes of this table, we show the benefits associated with the model average at 3%  discount rate;
 however we emphasize the importance and value of considering the full range of values, which is $310
 million - $1.8 billion for the proposed option. We provide climate benefit estimates based on additional
 discount rates in Section 4.2.
 2 The engineering compliance costs are annualized and include estimated revenue from electricity sales
 for landfills that are expected to generate revenue by using landfill gas for energy.
 3 While we expect that these avoided emissions will result in improvements in air quality and reductions
 in health effects associated with HAP, ozone, and paniculate matter (PM), we have determined that
 quantification of those benefits cannot be accomplished for this rule in a defensible way.  This is not to
 imply that these benefits do not exist; rather, it is a reflection of the difficulties in modeling the direct
 and indirect impacts of the reductions in emissions for this industrial sector with the data currently
 available.


ES.3 Results for Supplemental Proposed New Source Performance Standards


       For the Supplemental Proposed New Source Performance Standards for new or modified

MSW landfills, the key results of the RIA follow and are summarized  in Table ES-2:


Engineering Cost Analysis: To meet the proposed emission limits,  a MSW landfill is expected
to  install the least cost control for combusting the landfill gas. The control costs include the costs
to  install and operate gas collection. For landfills where the least cost control option was an
engine, the costs also include installing and operate one or more reciprocating internal
combustion engines to convert the landfill gas into electricity. Revenue from electricity sales was
incorporated into the net control costs using state-specific data on wholesale purchase prices. The
annualized costs also include testing  and monitoring costs. For this proposal, which tightens the
emissions threshold, the EPA estimated the nationwide incremental annualized compliance cost
in  2025 to be $8.5 million (2012$) using a 7% discount rate. Using a 3% discount rate, the
nationwide incremental annualized compliance cost in 2025 is estimated to be $7.1 million
(2012$).
                                             ES-3

-------
Emissions Analysis: In 2025, this proposal would achieve reductions of 300 Mg NMOC and
51,400 Mg methane (1.3 million Mg CCh-equivalents4) compared to the baseline. The proposal is
also expected to result in minor secondary air impacts, specifically an increase of 670 Mg CO2,
because more energy is required to operate the GCCS at some landfills than is produced by these
landfills through the burning of LFG in engines. These pollutants are associated with substantial
health, welfare and climate effects.

Benefits: The monetized benefits in this RIA include those from reducing 51,400 Mg methane,
which are valued using the social cost of methane (SC-CH/f), offset by the small increases in
CO2, which are valued using the social cost of carbon (SC-CCh). The EPA estimates that, in
2025, the proposal will yield monetized climate benefits of $36 million (2012$) to approximately
$210 million (2012$)5; the mean SC-CH4 at the 3% discount rate results in an estimate of about
$78 million (2012$) in 2025. The climate disbenefits associated with the increase of 670 Mg CO2
are estimated to be $0.03 million (2012$) in 2025. The benefits from reducing some air
pollutants have not been monetized in this analysis due to data, resource, and methodological
limitations, including reducing 300 Mg NMOC (including undetermined amounts of HAPs). We
assessed the benefits of these emission reductions qualitatively in this RIA.

Small Entity Analysis: The EPA performed a small business impacts analysis on the
Supplemental Proposed New Source Performance Standards for new or modified MSW landfills,
and as with the July 2014 proposed NSPS  subpart certifies that the proposed rule will not have a
Significant Impact on a Substantial Number of Small Entities (SISNOSE). The proposed revision
does not impact a substantial number of small entities, and the impact to these entities are not
significant. This is discussed in greater detail  in Section 7.4.

Economic Impacts: Because of the relatively low net compliance cost of this proposal
compared to the overall size of the MSW landfill industry, as well as the lack of appropriate
economic parameters or models, the EPA is unable to estimate the impacts of the proposal on the
supply and demand for MSW landfill services. However, the EPA does not believe the proposal
will lead to changes in supply and demand for landfill services or waste disposal costs, tipping
fees, or the amount of waste disposed in landfills. Hence, the overall economic impact of the
proposal should be minimal on the affected industries and their consumers.
4 A global warming potential of 25 is used to convert methane to CCh-equivalents.
5 The range of estimates reflects four SC-CH4 estimates: the mean across all models and scenarios using a 2.5
  percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount rate, and the 95th percentile of the pooled estimates from all models
  and scenarios using a 3% discount rate. See Section 4.2 for a complete discussion.


                                         ES-4

-------
Table ES-2  Summary of the Monetized Benefits, Costs, and Net Benefits for the
Supplemental Proposed New Source Performance Standards for MSW Landfills in 2025
(2012$)

                                       3% Discount Rate            7% Discount Rate
 Monetized Methane-related Benefits1                        $78 million
 Monetized CO2 disbenefits1                               $0.03 million
 Total Costs2                               $7.1 million                 $8.5 million
 Net Benefits                               $71 million                  $70 million
 , T       ..   , „    -.. o             Health effects of PM2 5 and ozone exposure from 300 Mg
 Non-monetized Benefits              XTA*/^/    j   j
                                   NMOC/yr reduced
                                   Health effects of HAP exposure from 300 Mg NMOC/yr
                                   reduced
                                   Visibility impairment
                                   Vegetation effects
 1 Monetized benefits include the climate-related benefits associated with the reduction of 51,400 Mg/yr
 methane, valued using the social cost of methane, and the net increase of 670 Mg/yr of CO2, valued
 using the social cost of carbon. The social cost of methane and social cost of carbon estimates are
 calculated with four different values of a one ton reduction (model average at 2.5 percent discount rate,
 3 percent, and 5 percent; 95th percentile at 3 percent). For the purposes of this table, we show the
 benefits associated with the model average at 3% discount rate; however we emphasize the importance
 and value of considering the full range of values, which is $36 million - $210  million for the proposed
 option. We provide climate benefit estimates based on additional discount rates in Section 4.2.
 2 The engineering compliance costs are annualized and include estimated revenue from electricity sales
 for landfills that are expected to generate revenue by using landfill gas for energy.
 3 While we expect that these avoided emissions will result in improvements in air quality and reductions
 in health effects associated with HAP, ozone, and paniculate matter (PM), we have determined that
 quantification of those benefits cannot be accomplished for this rule in a defensible way. This is not to
 imply that these benefits do not exist; rather, it is a reflection of the difficulties in modeling the direct
 and indirect impacts of the reductions in emissions for this industrial sector with the data currently
 available.	


ES.3 Organization of this Report


        The remainder of this  report details the methodology and the results of the RIA. Chapter

1 provides an introduction. Chapter 2 presents the industry profile for the municipal solid waste

landfill industry. Chapter 3 describes emissions, emissions control options, and engineering costs

of the Emission Guidelines for existing landfills. Chapter 4 presents estimates of the benefits of

emissions reductions from the Emission Guidelines for existing landfills. Chapter 5 present the

economic impacts, employment impacts, and small entity screening analysis for the Emission

Guidelines for existing landfills. Chapter 6 presents the comparison of the benefits and costs of

the Emission Guidelines for existing landfills, Chapter 7 presents an analysis of the supplemental

New Source Performance Standards (NSPS) for new or modified MSW landfills proposal,  and

Chapter 8 concludes with the  statutory and executive order reviews.
                                              ES-5

-------
                                 1   INTRODUCTION

1.1  Background

       The EPA is proposing revisions to the Emission Guidelines for existing Municipal Solid
Waste Landfills. The EPA is not statutorily obligated to conduct a review of the Emission
Guidelines, but has the discretionary authority to do so when circumstances indicate that this is
appropriate. Based on changes in the landfills industry and changes in size, ownership, and age
of landfills since the Emission Guidelines were promulgated in 1996, the EPA has concluded
that it is appropriate to review the landfills Emission Guidelines at this time. Based on our
review, we are proposing to lower the annual NMOC emissions threshold from 50 Mg/year to 34
Mg/year.

       In addition, the EPA is proposing Supplemental New Source  Performance Standards for
new or modified Municipal Solid Waste Landfills. On July 17, 2014, the EPA proposed a new
NSPS subpart that retained the same design capacity size threshold of 2.5 million m3 or 2.5
million Mg, but presented several options for revising the NMOC emission rate at which a MSW
landfill must install controls. Since presenting these options, the EPA has updated its model that
estimates the emission reduction and cost impacts based on public comments  and new data. As a
result of these data and model improvements, we are now proposing  to lower  the annual NMOC
emissions threshold from 50 Mg/year to 34 Mg/year.

       In accordance with Executive Order 12866, Executive Order  13563, OMB Circular A-4,
and the EPA's "Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses," the EPA prepared this RIA for
these "significant regulatory actions." These actions are economically significant regulatory
actions because they may have an annual effect on the economy of $100 million or more or
adversely affect in a material way the economy, a sector of the economy, productivity,
competition, jobs, the environment, public health or safety, or state, local, or tribal governments
or communities.6 In this RIA, the EPA presents a profile of the municipal solid waste industry in
6 The analysis in this draft RIA constitutes the economic assessment required by CAA section 317. In the EPA's
  judgment, the assessment is as extensive as practicable taking into account the EPA's time, resources, and other
  duties and authorities.
                                           1-1

-------
the United States and an analysis of the costs and emissions reductions associated with a range of
regulatory options, including the option chosen for proposal. The EPA drew upon a
comprehensive database of existing landfills for this analysis. However, this dataset was missing
some landfill data for recent years (2010-2014) and included incomplete data for many landfills.
Thus, model landfills were created to represent the recent landfill data that were not included in
the dataset. The model landfills were developed by evaluating the most recently opened existing
landfills and assuming that the sizes and locations of landfills opening during 2010-2014 would
be similar to the sizes and locations of landfills that opened in the most recent complete 5 years
of data (2005-2010). The impacts of the proposed Emission Guidelines for existing MSW
landfills shown  in this RIA are expressed as the incremental difference between facilities
complying with the current Emission Guidelines for existing MSW landfills (40 CFR part 60,
subpart Cc) and facilities that would be required to comply with proposed subpart Cf Likewise,
the impacts of the proposed NSPS for new or modified MSW landfills shown in this RIA are
expressed as the incremental difference between facilities complying with the current NSPS for
new  or modified MSW landfills (40 CFR part 60, subpart WWW)  and facilities that would be
required to comply with proposed subpart XXX. All impacts are shown for the year 2025. The
EPA is assessing impacts in year 2025 as a representative year for  the both the landfills Emission
Guidelines and NSPS. While the year 2025 differs somewhat from the expected first year of
implementation for the Emission Guidelines (year 2020), the number of existing landfills
required to install controls under the proposed 2.5/34 option in year 2025 is comparable (within 2
percent of those required to control in the estimated first year of implementation. Further, year
2025 represents a year in which several of the landfills subject to control requirements have had
to expand their GCCS according the expansion lag times set forth in proposed subpart Cf. While
the analysis focuses on impacts in 2025, results for alternative years are also presented.

       The EPA certifies that the proposed Emission Guidelines for existing landfills will not
have a  Significant Impact on a Substantial Number of Small Entities (SISNOSE) because the
proposed rule will not impose any requirements on small entities. Specifically, Emission
Guidelines established under CAA section 11 l(d) do not impose any requirements on regulated
entities and, thus, will not have a significant economic impact upon a substantial number of
small entities. The EPA also certifies that the supplemental proposed NSPS for new or modified
MSW landfills also will not have a significant impact on a substantial number of small entities
                                          1-2

-------
(SISNOSE). The proposed revision does not impact a substantial number of small entities, and
the impact to these entities are not significant. This is discussed in greater detail in Section 7.4.

1.2   Statement of Need for Policy Action

1.2.1   Protection of Human Health and the Environment

       The EPA has concluded, after reviewing data on MSW landfills, that a review of the
Emission Guidelines for existing MSW landfills is appropriate at this time. In addition, the EPA
is proposing Supplemental New Source Performance Standards for new or modified Municipal
Solid Waste Landfills. To ensure that public health,  safety, and the environment are protected,
the EPA must ensure that emissions of methane, VOC,  and HAP from MSW landfills are
limited. The pollutant regulated under rules affecting landfills is "MSW landfill emissions".
Municipal solid waste landfill emissions, also commonly referred to as landfill  gas (LFG), are a
collection of air pollutants, including methane and NMOC, some of which are toxic.7 The 1996
NSPS/EG regulated nonmethane organic compounds (NMOC) as a surrogate for MSW landfill
emissions but also considered significant methane reductions that could be achieved. In this EG
and supplemental NSPS proposal, we are proposing to lower the annual NMOC emissions
threshold from 50 Mg/year to 34 Mg/year. The NMOC portion of LFG can contain a variety of
air pollutants, including VOC  and various organic HAP. VOC emissions are precursors to both
fine particulate matter (PM2.s) and ozone formation, while methane is a greenhouse gas and a
precursor to global ozone formation. As described in Chapter 4, these pollutants are associated
with substantial health effects, climate  effects, and other welfare effects. Thus,  the proposed rule
is expected to reduce human morbidity and premature mortality due to exposure to PM2.5, in
addition to providing human health and ecosystem benefits due to reduced emissions of methane
and HAP, and improved visibility due to reduced PM levels.
' LFG is composed of approximately 50 percent methane, 50 percent CCh, and less than 1 percent NMOC. (Source:
   EPA. Compilation of Air Pollution Emission Factors, Publication AP-42, Draft Section 2.4 Municipal Solid
   Waste Landfills. October 2008. Available at http://www.epa.gov/ttn/chief/ap42/ch02/draft/d02s04.pdf.) While
   this composition is typical of LFG generated from established waste (waste that has typically been in place for at
   least a year), the quantity and composition of LFG does vary over the lifetime of the landfill. See Section 2.5 for
   more discussion.
                                            1-3

-------
1.2.2   Need for Regulatory Intervention Because of Market Failure

       The U.S. Office of Management and Budget (OMB) directs regulatory agencies to
demonstrate the need for a major rule. If the rule is intended to correct a market failure, the
regulatory impact analysis must show that a market failure exists and that it cannot be resolved
by measures other than Federal regulation. Market failures are categorized by OMB as
externalities, market power, or inadequate or asymmetric information. The only of these three
categories that applies to MSW landfills is air pollution as an externality, which is discussed in
the following section.

1.2.2.1  Air Pollution as an Externality
       Air pollution is an example of a negative externality. This means that, in the absence of
government regulation, the decisions of generators of air pollution do not fully reflect the costs
associated with that pollution. For an MSW landfill operator, pollution from landfill gas is a by-
product that can be ignored or disposed of cheaply by venting it to the atmosphere. Left to their
own devices, many MSW landfill operators may choose to treat air as a free good and not
internalize the damage cause by emissions. NMOC and Greenhouse Gas (GHG) emissions
impose costs on society, such as negative health and welfare impacts that are not reflected in the
market price of the MSW landfill services being provided.  This damage is borne by society, and
the people who are adversely affected by the pollution are not able to collect compensation to
offset their costs. They cannot collect compensation because the adverse effects, like odor and
increased risks of morbidity and mortality, are by and large non-market goods. That is,  they are
goods that are not explicitly and routinely traded in organized free markets.
1.3   Organization of this Report

       The remainder of this report details the methodology and the results of the RIA. Chapter
2 presents the industry profile for the municipal solid waste landfill industry. Chapter 3 describes
emissions, emissions control options, and engineering costs of the Emission Guidelines for
existing landfills. Chapter 4 presents estimates of the benefits  of emissions reductions from the
Emission Guidelines for existing landfills. Chapter 5 present the economic impacts, employment
                                           1-4

-------
impacts, and small entity screening analysis for the Emission Guidelines for existing landfills.
Chapter 6 presents the comparison of the benefits and costs of the Emission Guidelines for
existing landfills, Chapter 7 presents an analysis of the supplemental New Source Performance
Standards (NSPS) for new and modified MSW landfills proposal, and Chapter 8 concludes with
the statutory and executive order reviews.

1.4  References

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2008. Compilation of Air Pollution Emission
       Factors, Publication AP-42, Draft Section 2.4 Municipal Solid Waste Landfills. October
       2008. Available at http://www.epa.gov/ttn/chief/ap42/ch02/draft/d02s04.pdf
                                           1-5

-------
                               2   INDUSTRY PROFILE

2.1  Introduction

       Municipal solid waste (MSW) is the stream of garbage collected by sanitation services
from homes, businesses, and institutions. MSW typically consists of metals, glass, plastics,
paper, wood, organics, mixed categories, and composite products. The majority of collected
MSW that is not recycled is typically sent to landfills—engineered areas of land where waste is
deposited, compacted, and covered. The New Source Performance Standards (NSPS) and the
state and federal plans implementing the emission guidelines (EG) for MSW landfills regulate air
emissions from landfills that receive household waste as defined in 40 CFR 60.751. These MSW
landfills can also receive other types of waste, such as construction and demolition debris,
industrial wastes, or nonhazardous sludge. MSW landfills are designed  to protect the
environment from contaminants which may be present in the solid waste stream and as such are
required to comply with federal Resource Conservation and Recovery Act (RCRA) regulations
or equivalent state regulations, which include standards related to location restrictions, composite
liners requirements, leachate collection and removal systems, operating practices, groundwater
monitoring requirements, closure and post-closure care requirements, corrective action
provisions, and financial assurance (EPA, 2012b).
       EPA estimates the total amount of MSW generated in the United States in 2012 was
approximately 251 million tons, a 20 percent increase from 1990. Despite increased waste
generation, the amount of MSW deposited in landfills decreased from about 145 million tons in
1990 to 135 million tons in 2012. This decline is due to a significant increase in the amount of
waste recovered for recycling and composting as well as that combusted for energy recovery
(EPA, 2014a).  The number of active MSW landfills in the United States has decreased from
approximately 7,900 in 1988 to approximately 1,800  in 2014 (EPA, 2010;  WBJ, 2014).
       Landfills are different than many other traditionally regulated emissions source
categories. Typically, entities regulated for air emissions are involved in manufacturing or
production and their emissions are directly related to  processes involved in creating products
(e.g., vehicles, bricks) or commodities (e.g., natural gas, oil). When manufacturing or production
facilities  cease to operate, their emissions typically cease. Landfills are  a service industry—a
repository for waste that needs to be properly disposed—and their emissions are a by-product of
                                          2-1

-------
the deposition of that waste. Landfills continue to emit air pollution for many years after the last
waste is deposited.
       Landfill gas (LFG) is a by-product of the decomposition of organic material in MSW in
anaerobic conditions in landfills. LFG contains roughly 50 percent methane and 50 percent
carbon dioxide, with less than 1 percent non-methane organic compounds (NMOC) and trace
amounts of inorganic compounds. The amount of LFG created primarily depends on the quantity
of waste and its composition and moisture content as well as the design and management
practices at the site. LFG can be collected and combusted in flares or energy recovery devices to
reduce emissions.  MSW landfills receive approximately 69 percent of the total waste generated
in the United States and produce 95 percent of landfill emissions. The remainder of the emissions
is generated by industrial waste landfills (EPA, 2015h).
       Entities potentially regulated under Standards of Performance for Municipal Solid Waste
Landfills include owners of MSW landfills and owners of combustion devices that burn
untreated LFG. Firms engaged in the collection and disposal of refuse in a landfill operation are
classified under the North American Industry Classification System (NAICS) codes Solid Waste
Landfill (562212)  and Administration of Air and Water Resource and Solid Waste Management
Programs (924110).
       Landfills are owned by private companies, government (local, state, or federal), or
individuals. In 2014, 58 percent of active MSW landfills were owned by public entities while
42 percent were privately owned (EPA, 2014c). Affected entities comprise establishments
primarily engaged in operating landfills for the disposal of non-hazardous solid waste; or the
combined activity of collecting and/or hauling non-hazardous waste materials within a local area
and operating landfills for the disposal of non-hazardous solid waste. This industry also includes
government establishments primarily engaged in the administration and regulation of solid waste
management programs.
       Private companies that own landfills range in size from very small businesses to large
businesses with billions of dollars in annual revenue. Public landfill owners include cities,
counties/parishes,  regional authorities, state governments, and the  federal government (including
military branches, Bureau of Land Management, Department of Agriculture, Forest Service, and
Department of the Interior - National Park Service).
                                          2-2

-------
2.2  Waste Stream Background

2.2.1   Municipal Waste

2.2.1.1  Generation ofMSW
       MSW is generally defined as nonhazardous waste from household, commercial, and
institutional sources. These three broad categories of primary MSW generators are described as:
       •  Household - solid waste from single-and multiple-family homes, hotels and motels,
          bunkhouses, ranger stations, crew quarters, campgrounds, picnic grounds, and day-
          use recreation areas.
       •  Commercial - solid waste from stores, offices, restaurants, warehouses, and other
          nonmanufacturing activities.
       •  Institutional - solid waste from public works (such as street sweepings and tree and
          brush trimmings), schools and colleges, hospitals, prisons, and similar public or
          quasi-public buildings. Infectious and hazardous waste from these generators are
          managed separately from MSW.
       Households  are the primary source of MSW, accounting for 55 to 65 percent of total
MSW generated, followed by the commercial sector (EPA, 2011). Waste from commercial and
institutional locations amounts to 35 to 45 percent of total MSW (EPA, 2011). The industrial
sector manages most of its own solid residuals by recycling,  reuse, or self-disposal in industrial
waste landfills. For this reason industry directly contributes a very small share of the MSW flow,
although some industrial waste does end up in MSW landfills.
       Various underlying factors influence the trends in the quantity of MSW generated over
time. These factors include changes in population, individual purchasing power and disposal
patterns, trends in product  packaging, and technological changes that affect disposal habits and
the nature of materials disposed. Generators of MSW provide most of the demand for services
that collect, treat, or dispose  of MSW. Fluctuations in the quantity of MSW generated and
changes in the cost and pricing structure of disposal services result in varying demand for landfill
services.
       Most MSW generators are charged a flat fee for disposal services, which can be paid
through taxes for household  garbage collection. This structure may provide little economic
                                           2-3

-------
incentive to lower waste disposal or to divert waste through recycling because generators are
charged the same price regardless of the quantity of waste disposed. Less common are unit price
programs, such as "pay-as-you-throw" (PAYT). In PAYT programs, each unit of waste disposed
has an explicit price, such that the total fee paid for MSW services increases with the quantity of
waste discarded.  Hence, the unit price can act as a disincentive to dispose of excess waste and
also encourages recycling (Callan, 2006; Shin, 2014).

2.2.1.2  Landfills Covered Under the EG
       The Landfills EG applies only to landfills that accept "household waste" as defined in 40
CFR 60.751, which states "household waste means any solid waste (including garbage, trash,
and sanitary waste in septic tanks) derived from households (including, but not limited to, single
and multiple residences,  hotels and motels, bunkhouses, ranger stations, crew quarters,
campgrounds, picnic grounds, and day-use recreation areas)." Some of the MSW landfills
subject to the Landfills EG may also receive other types of wastes, such as commercial,
industrial, and institutional solid waste, nonhazardous sludge, and construction and demolition
debris.

2.2.1.3  Trends in Per Capita Waste Sent to Landfills
       In 2012, Americans generated about 251 million tons of trash. More than 65 million tons
of this material was recycled and more than 21 million tons was composted, equivalent to a 34.5
percent recycling rate (EPA, 2014a). In addition, about 29 million tons of waste was combusted
for energy recovery (-12 percent) (EPA, 2014a). After recycling, composting, and combustion
with energy recovery, the net per capita discard rate to landfills was 2.36 pounds per person per
day in 2012 (EPA, 2014a). This is a 6 percent decrease from the 2.51 per capita discard rate in
1960, when minimal recycling occurred in the United States (see Table 2-1).
       Since 1990, the total amount of MSW going to landfills has dropped by about  10 million
tons, from 145 million to 135 million tons in 2012 (EPA, 2014a). While the number of U.S.
MSW landfills has steadily declined over the years, the average landfill size has increased. At the
national level, landfill  capacity appears to be sufficient, although it is limited in some  areas
(EPA, 2014a).
                                          2-4

-------
Table 2-1  Generation and Discards of MSW, 1960 to 2012 (in pounds per person per
day)8
Activity
Generation

Discards to landfill a

Discards to landfill
(% of total generation)
1960

2.68

2.51

94%
1970

3.25

3.02

93%
1980

3.66

3.24

89%
1990

4.57

3.19

70%
2000

4.74

2.73

58%
2005

4.69

2.63

56%
2008

4.55

2.46

54%
2010

4.44

2.41

54%
2011

4.40

2.36

54%
2012

4.38

2.36

54%
a Discards after recovery minus combustion with energy recovery. Discards include combustion without energy
  recovery.
2.2.1.4   Composition of MSW Sent to Landfills
       In 2012, organic materials continued to be the largest component of discarded MSW.
Yard trimmings and food scraps account for 29.8 percent and paper and paperboard account for
another 14.8 percent. Plastics comprise 17.6 percent while metals and wood make up 9.0 percent
and 8.2 percent, respectively. Rubber, leather, and textiles combined account for 11.2 percent
and glass accounts for 5.1 percent. Other miscellaneous materials account for the remaining
4.3 percent of the MSW discarded in 2012 (EPA, 2014a). Figure 2-1 displays material
composition percentages of the MSW discard stream in 2012, and Table 2-2 shows the amounts
of different materials discarded in the MSW stream from 1960 to 2012.
8 Table adapted from U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 2014. "Municipal Solid Waste Generation, Recycling,
   and Disposal in the United States: Facts and Figures for 2012." Table 4. EPA-530-F-14-001. Washington, DC:
   U.S. EPA. . Accessed January 6, 2015.
                                            2-5

-------
                                                                     i Food waste
                                                                     i Wood
                                                                      Plastics
                                                                     i Glass
                                                                     i Metals
                                                                      Yard trimmings
                                                                      Paper & paperboard
                                                                      Other
                                                                      Rubber, leather & textiles
Figure 2-1  Material Composition of the MSW Discard Stream, 20129
9 Figure adapted from U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 2014. "Municipal Solid Waste Generation,
Recycling, and Disposal in the United States: Facts and Figures for 2012." Figure 7. EPA-530-F-14-001.
Washington, DC: U.S. EPA. . Accessed
January 6, 2015.
                                                2-6

-------
Table 2-2  Materials Discarded" In the MSW Stream, 1960 to 2012 (in thousands of tons)
                                                                                            10
Wastes
Paper and Paperboard
Glass
Metals
Plastics
Rubber and Leather
Textiles
Wood
Other Materials'3
Food Waste
Yard Trimmings
Miscellaneous Inorganic Wastes
Total MSW Discarded
1960
24,910
6,620
10,770
390
1,510
1,710
3,030
70
12,200
20,000
1,300
82,510
1970
37,540
12,580
13,350
2,900
2,720
1,980
3,720
470
12,800
23,200
1,780
113,040
1980
43,420
14,380
14,290
6,810
4,070
2,370
7,010
2,020
13,000
27,500
2,250
137,120
1990
52,500
10,470
12,580
16,760
5,420
5,150
12,080
2,510
23,860
30,800
2,900
175,030
2000
50,180
9,890
12,340
24,070
5,850
8,160
12,200
3,020
30,020
14,760
3,500
173,990
2005
42,880
9,950
13,410
27,600
6,240
9,680
12,960
3,080
32,240
12,210
3,690
173,940
2010
26,740
8,400
14,500
28,790
6,120
11,100
13,430
3,370
34,770
14,200
3,840
165,260
2012
24,260
8,370
14,760
28,950
6,180
12,080
13,410
3,300
34,690
14,370
3,900
164,270
 a Discards after materials and compost recovery. In this table, discards include combustion with energy recovery.
   Does not include construction and demolition debris, industrial process wastes, or certain other wastes.
  Includes electrolytes in batteries and fluff pulp, feces, and urine in disposable diapers.
   Details may not add to totals due to rounding.

2.2.2   Consolidation of Waste Streams

        Collection and transportation are necessary components of all MSW management
systems regardless of the specific disposal options. Collections of MSW vary by service
arrangements between local governments and collectors and by level of service provided to
households. Depending on the arrangement type and other considerations for particular
jurisdictions, MSW being sent to landfills may be deposited in a local landfill or routed to a
regional landfill through a transfer process. Local  landfills are generally located in the
communities in which they serve whereas regional landfills are often located outside of the
communities they serve and receive waste from several cities and towns.
        Solid waste transfer is the process in which collection vehicles unload their waste at
centrally located transfer stations. Transfer stations can minimize hauling costs by decreasing the
number of drivers and vehicles hauling waste to disposal sites and reducing the turn-around time
10 Table adapted from U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 2014. "Municipal Solid Waste Generation,
   Recycling, and Disposal in the United States Tables and Figures for 2012." Table 3. Washington, DC: U.S. EPA.
   . Accessed January 15, 2015.
                                              2-7

-------
of vehicles because they do not have to haul waste to distant regional landfills. Smaller loads are
consolidated into larger vehicles, usually tractor-trailer trucks, trains, or barges, which are better
suited for the long-distance hauls often required to reach the final disposal site, often a regional
landfill. As public opposition to local MSW disposal facilities increases and the cost of disposal
at locations near generators rise, long-distance hauls to regional landfills are becoming more
common.

2.3  Disposal Facility Background

2.3.1   Technical Background on Landfills as a Source Category

       An MSW landfill refers to an area of land or an excavation where MSW is placed for
permanent disposal. MSW landfills do not include land application units, surface impoundments,
injection wells, or waste piles. Modern MSW landfills are well-engineered disposal facilities that
are sited, designed, operated, and monitored to protect human health and the environment from
pollutants that may be present in the solid waste stream (EPA, 2012b).

2.3.1.1  Landfill Siting and Permitting
       MSW landfills are required to comply with federal regulations contained in Subtitle D of
RCRA [40 CFR  part 258], or equivalent state regulations. RCRA requirements include location
restrictions that ensure landfills are constructed away from environmentally-sensitive areas,
including fault zones, wetlands, flood plains, or other restricted areas (EPA, 2012b).  Site
selection for landfills is an integral part of the design process.

       Construction and operating permit applications  for new landfills must be submitted to and
approved by state and local regulatory agencies as  part of the siting and design process.  Often,
states require a registered professional engineer to  design the landfill (Guyer, 2009).  Additional
permits must be  issued for each expansion of the landfill from its originally permitted waste
design capacity and footprint area. New or modified landfills may also require air permits under
the New Source  Review (NSR) permitting program, which includes Prevention of Significant
Deterioration (PSD) requirements for landfills sited in attainment areas, or areas where the air
                                           2-8

-------
quality meets the National Ambient Air Quality Standards (NAAQS), and more stringent NSR
requirements for landfills located in non-attainment areas.

       Developing a new landfill or expanding an existing landfill has become increasingly
difficult, especially in metropolitan areas, due to the urbanization of suitable sites, permitting
barriers, elevated land costs, and other factors. If a new landfill is proposed or when expansion
plans for existing landfills are announced, adjacent communities may mount opposition that can
hinder issuance of required permits and thus development of the landfill (Alva, 2010).

2.3.1.2  Landfill Operations
       The two most common methods for active disposal of waste into landfills are the area fill
method and the trench method. The area fill method involves waste placement in a large open
section of a lined landfill and then spreading and compacting waste in uniform layers using
heavy equipment. The trench method of filling waste in a modern landfill involves placing and
compacting waste into a trench and then using soil and other materials from the trench
excavation as daily cover. Local conditions often determine the most appropriate method for a
particular landfill, and a combination of the two methods can be utilized. The trench method is
generally less desirable than the area fill method, mostly due to the expense of lining side  slopes
to protect groundwater from leachate leakage and restrict gas migration (Guyer,  2009).
       As required by Subtitle D of RCRA, cover material is applied on top of the waste mass at
the end of each day to prevent odors and fires and reduce litter, insects, and rodents. Materials
used as daily cover include soil, compost, incinerator ash, foam, and tarps (NW&RA, 2008).
Similarly, intermediate  cover is used when an area of the landfill is not expected to receive waste
or a cap for an extended period of time. Intermediate covers have traditionally consisted of layers
of soil, geotextiles, or other materials. The reasons for using intermediate cover are similar to
those for using daily cover and may also include erosion control.
       It is important to maintain anaerobic conditions within the landfill waste mass to avoid
excess air infiltration that can cause fires. Landfill fires can be avoided by closely monitoring
landfill conditions and maintaining the landfill as a controlled  facility. If an active LFG
collection system is installed, then gas wells are monitored to ensure oxygen is not being pulled
into the landfill due to excessive vacuum levels.
                                           2-9

-------
2.3.1.3  Landfill Closure
       Once an area of the landfill, or cell, has reached its permitted height, that cell is closed
and a low permeability cap made of compacted clay or synthetic material is installed to prevent
infiltration of precipitation. To divert water off of the top of the landfill, a granular drainage layer
is placed on top of the low-permeability barrier layer. A protective cover is placed on top of the
filter blanket and topsoil is placed as the final layer to support vegetation. The final cap and
cover inhibit soil erosion and provide odor and LFG control (NW&RA, 2008). If an LFG
collection system is in place, then expansion of the collection system into filled cells or areas of
the landfill may require additional gas wells to be installed soon after these cells are closed and
capped. Gas collection system design is discussed further in Section 2.6.
       RCRA Subtitle D regulations contain closure and post-closure care requirements,
including written closure and post-closure care plans and maintaining the final cover, leachate
collection system, and groundwater and LFG monitoring systems. The required post-closure care
period is 30  years from site closure, but this can be shortened or extended if approved by state
regulatory agencies (EPA, 2012c).

2.3.1.4  Management of Liquids
       Leachate is the liquid that passes through  the landfilled waste and strips contaminants
from the waste as it percolates. Precipitation is the primary source of this liquid. To prevent
water pollution and protect soil beneath, RCRA Subtitle D  requires liners for landfills as well as
leachate collection and removal and groundwater monitoring systems. Composite liner systems
are used along the bottom  and sides of landfills as impermeable barriers and are typically
constructed with layers of natural materials with low permeability (e.g., compacted clay) and/or
synthetic materials (e.g., high-density polyethylene) (NW&RA, 2008). Landfill liner systems
also  help prevent offsite migration of LFG.
       Leachate collection systems remove leachate from the landfill as it collects on the liner
using a perforated collection pipe placed in a drainage layer (e.g., gravel). Waste is placed
directly above the leachate collection system in layers. Collected leachate can be treated  on site
or transported off site to treatment facilities. For landfills with LFG collection systems, LFG
condensate can be combined with leachate prior to treatment.
                                           2-10

-------
       Although traditional landfills tend to minimize the infiltration of liquids into a landfill
using liners, covers, and caps (sometimes referred to as "dry tombs"), some landfills recirculate
all or a portion of leachate collected to increase the amount of moisture within the waste mass.
This practice of leachate recirculation results in a faster anaerobic biodegradation process and
increased rate of LFG generation. Similarly, landfills may introduce liquids other than leachate,
such as sludge and industrial wastewater. Conventional landfills typically have in-situ moisture
contents of approximately 20 percent, whereas landfills recirculating leachate or other liquids
may maintain moisture contents ranging from 35 to 65 percent (EPA, 2012d). Often, landfills
injecting or recirculating liquids are termed bioreactors, but bioreactor landfills are defined
differently amongst industry and regulatory agencies. In addition, bioreactor landfills may have
air injected in a controlled manner to further accelerate biodegradation of the waste, which
occurs for aerobic and hybrid bioreactor configurations.

2.3.2  Ownership and Characteristics of Landfills

       Since the 1980s, the number of active MSW landfills in the United States has decreased
by approximately 75 percent (from -7,900 in 1988 to -1,800 in 2014) and the share of sites that
are publicly owned has also decreased—from 83 percent in 1984 to 58 percent in 2014 (EPA,
2010; WBJ, 2014; O'Brien, 2006; EPA, 2014c). However, the overall volume of disposal
capacity has remained fairly constant, indicating a trend of growing individual landfill capacity
(SWANA, 2007). Based on landfills reporting to the EPA Greenhouse Gas Reporting Program
(GHGRP) that they were actively accepting waste in 2013, privately owned sites represented 73
percent of the overall permitted MSW landfill capacity and 73 percent of the MSW landfilled in
that year, an indication that private landfills are likely to be significantly larger than public ones
(GHGRP, 2013). Among these reporting sites, the average annual amount of MSW disposed at
public sites was just under  175,000 short tons, whereas the average private site landfilled about
427,000 short tons of MSW per year—further evidence that publicly owned landfills are
generally much smaller than their private counterparts (GHGRP, 2013).
       EPA recognized as early as 2002 that a nationwide trend in solid waste disposal is toward
the construction of larger, more remote, regional landfills. Economic considerations, influenced
by regulatory and social forces, are compelling factors that likely led to the closure of many
existing sites and to the idea of regional landfills (EPA, 2002b). The passage of federal
                                          2-11

-------
environmental regulations that affected landfills (e.g., RCRA in 1976, Subtitle D of RCRA in
1991), established requirements which made it more expensive to properly construct, operate,
maintain, and close landfills (O'Brien, 2006; EPA 2012e; EPA, 2002b). Large, private
companies are better able to accommodate the increased costs of owning a landfill, since owning
multiple sites,  many of which have large capacities, provides an economy of scale for cost
expenditures (O'Brien, 2006). To offset the high cost of constructing and maintaining a modern
landfill, facility owners construct large facilities that attract high volumes of waste from a large
geographic area, often using shipments from rail or truck (BioCycle, 2014a). By maintaining a
high volume of incoming waste, landfill owners can keep tipping fees relatively low, which
subsequently attracts more business (EPA, 2002b).
       As older, public landfills near their capacities, communities must decide whether to
construct new  landfills or seek other options. Many find the cost of upgrading existing facilities
or constructing new landfills to be prohibitively high, and opt to close existing facilities. Also,
public opposition often makes siting new landfills near population centers difficult and adequate
land may not be available near densely populated or urban areas. Many communities are finding
that the most economically viable solution to their waste disposal needs is shipping their waste to
regional landfills. In these circumstances,  a transfer station serves as the critical link in making
the shipment of waste  to distant facilities cost-effective (EPA, 2002b).
       Waste transfer stations are facilities where MSW is unloaded from collection vehicles
and reloaded into long-distance transport vehicles for delivery to landfills or other
treatment/disposal facilities. By combining the loads of several waste collection trucks into a
single shipment, communities and waste management companies can save money on the labor
and operating costs of transporting waste to a distant disposal site.  They can also reduce the total
number of vehicular miles traveled to and from the disposal site(s) (EPA, 2012f). Given the
dramatic decrease in the number of active landfills in the past 25 years, transfer stations play an
important part in facilitating the movement of solid waste from the areas in which it originates to
its end location, often  a large,  centrally located landfill. The role of transfer stations in waste
management has become even more prominent with the increase in the number of "regional"
landfills—sites with very large capacities, often located in remote areas, and usually privately
owned. As more and more publicly owned landfills reach capacity and close, the waste must go
somewhere, and often that is to a regional landfill by way of a transfer station.
                                          2-12

-------
       There are more than 100 private companies that own and/or operate currently active
MSW landfills, ranging from large companies with numerous landfills throughout the country to
local businesses that own a single landfill (EPA, 2014c). The handling of MSW in the United
States generated $55 billion of revenue in 2011, of which landfilling contributed $13 billion
(WBJ, 2012a). In terms of their overall 2013 revenue, the top two companies that own and/or
operate MSW landfills in the United States were Waste Management ($13.98 billion) and
Republic Services  ($8.42 billion), which together accounted for approximately 40 percent of the
solid waste management revenue share in 2013 (Bloomberg, 2014WM; Bloomberg, 2014RSG).
The next tier of companies involved in landfill management includes Clean Harbors ($3.51
billion), Progressive Waste Solutions ($2.03 billion), and Waste Connections ($1.93 billion)
(Bloomberg, 2014CLH; Bloomberg, 2014BIN; Bloomberg, 2014WCN). Table 2-3 contains a
summary of the 2013 revenue for the top five companies, as well as information about their
MSW landfills  and transfer stations.
                                         2-13

-------
Table 2-3  Top 5 Waste Management Companies That Owned or Operated MSW
Landfills in the United States in 2013a
Company
Waste Management
(Bloomberg,
2014WM)
Republic Services
(Bloomberg,
2014RSG)
Clean Harbors
(Bloomberg,
2014CLH)
Progressive Waste
Solutions
(Bloomberg,
2014BIN)
Waste Connections
(Bloomberg,
2014WCN)
2013
Revenue
(billion $)
13.98
8.42
3.51
2.03
1.93
No. of MSW
Landfills Owned
and/or Operated
267
190 active/
124 closed
2
N/A
42 active
MSW
Received at
Landfills
(million tons)
93.8
N/A
N/A
N/A
19.5
No. of Transfer
Stations Owned
and/or
Operated
300
199
N/A
N/A
61
a Ranking of top five companies adapted from "The 2013 Waste Age 100". . Accessed January 16, 2015.
N/A = Not available.

       The industry that deposits MSW in landfills encompasses a wide range of job types,
including garbage collectors, truck drivers, heavy equipment operators, engineers of various
disciplines, specialized technicians, executives, MSW department directors, administrative staff,
weigh scale operators, salespersons, and landfill operations managers. In 2012, 1,290 private
establishments had 15,426 employees in the continental United States under NAICS 562212
(Solid Waste Landfill) (Census, 2012). In 2013, solid waste management departments of local
governments reported 95,674 full-time employees and 14,638 part-time employees (Census,
2013); however, statistics are not readily available solely for landfill-related aspects of these
departments. As the population continues to grow in the United States the amount of waste
generated will continue to increase, but the amount of waste landfilled may remain the same or
decrease (EPA, 2015h). Employment within the waste management industry overall will likely
remain strong, perhaps with an increased shift of employees from the public sector to the private
sector.
                                          2-14

-------
2.4  Costs and Revenue Streams for Landfills

2.4.1   Major Cost Components for Landfills

       EPA promulgated Criteria for Municipal Solid Waste Landfills (40 CFR part 258) under
the RCRA on October 9, 1991 (EPA, 2012g). The law requires that non-hazardous MSW be
disposed of in specially designed sanitary landfills. The criteria include location restrictions,
design and  operating standards, groundwater monitoring requirements, corrective actions,
financial assurance requirements, LFG migration controls, closure requirements, and post-
closure requirements (EPA, 2012g). It can cost more than $1 million per acre to construct,
operate, and close a landfill in compliance with these regulations (Fitzwater, 2012).
       Landfill costs are site specific and vary based on factors such as terrain, soil type,
climate, site restrictions, regulatory issues, type and amount of waste disposed, preprocessing,
and potential for groundwater contamination. Landfill costs fall into the following categories:
site development, construction, equipment purchases, operation, closure, and post-closure.
       Site development includes site surveys, engineering and design studies, and permit
package fees. Surveys are necessary to determine if a potential site is feasible. Permits are
required from local, state, and federal governments. As  an example, engineering design and a
permit application for an MSW landfill in Kentucky can cost approximately $750,000 to
$1.2 million (KY SWB, 2012).
       Construction costs encompass building the landfill cells as well as development of
permanent onsite structures needed to operate the landfill. Cortland County, New York estimated
that the cost for site development and cell construction (not including onsite building
construction)  for a 224.5-acre site would be approximately $500,000 per acre (EnSol, 2010). In
2005, a series of articles was written that estimated costs for a hypothetical  landfill based on
known market conditions and cost data. The theoretical landfill had a design capacity of
4 million cubic yards and a footprint of 33 acres. The study determined that the cost of
constructing a landfill of this size would be between $300,000 and $800,000 per acre. Table 2-4
summarizes typical construction costs per acre by individual task  for this example site (Duffy,
2005a).
                                          2-15

-------
Table 2-4  Typical Costs Per Acre for Components of Landfill Construction (Duffy, 2005a)
Task
Clear and Grub
Site Survey
Excavation
Perimeter Berm
Clay Liner
Geomembrane
Geocomposite
Granular Soil
Leachate System
QA/QC
TOTAL
Low End
$1,000
$5,000
$100,000
$10,000
$32,000
$24,000
$33,000
$48,000
$8,000
$75,000
$336,000
High End
$3,000
$8,000
$330,000
$16,000
$162,000
$35,000
$44,000
$64,000
$12,000
$100,000
$774,000
       Excavation of the landfill site comprises a notable portion of the construction costs.
Installation of a landfill liner can vary greatly in cost depending on the site's geology. Most
states require only a single liner and leachate collection system for MSW, but requirements vary
for the minimum thickness of clay liners. Landfill sites may have good quality clay located on
site that would significantly lower the cost of a clay liner. The QA/QC task in Table 2-4 refers to
management and quality oversight which is usually performed by independent third-party
consultants.
       For the hypothetical landfill in the study, total building and additional structure costs
could total between $1.165 million and $1.77 million.  Operation of the landfill requires a truck
scale, scale house, wheel wash facility, and buildings to accommodate an office and provide
space for maintenance. The cost of each building structure varies depending on its functions and
could range from $10 to $100 per square foot. Office buildings cost more while  maintenance
buildings and tool sheds cost less. In addition, fencing around the facility and roadways are
required and add to the costs (Duffy, 2005a).
       Operating costs of the example landfill include staffing, equipment (payments and
maintenance), leachate treatment, and facilities and general maintenance. Landfill operations and
maintenance activities are performed using a variety of heavy construction equipment with
operating costs dependent on fuel, repairs, and maintenance. Operating costs are relatively small
                                          2-16

-------
when compared to the capital costs; estimated annual operating costs from this study are (Duffy,
2005a):
       •  Operations (equipment, staff, facilities and general maintenance): $500,000.
       •  Leachate collection and treatment (assumes sewer connection and discharge cost of
          $0.02/gallon): $10,000.
       •  Environmental sampling and monitoring (groundwater, surface water, air gas,
          leachate): $30,000.
       •  Engineering services (consulting firms and in-house staff): $60,000.
       Once a landfill no longer accepts waste, the closure process includes the installation of a
final cover and cap. Capital costs for installation of a cap can run between $80,000 and $500,000
per acre. For example, at a Maryland sanitary landfill costs were $150,000 per acre (MDE,
2012). The capping costs for a 249.4-acre site in Cortland County, New York were estimated to
be approximately $134,000 per acre. Factors influencing these costs include the materials used
for the cap, site topography, and the availability of clay or soil  suitable for use as the cover.
Similar to the costs of the clay liner during the construction of the landfill, availability of nearby
clay would significantly reduce this cost (EnSol, 2010).
       The closure process can include the installation of an LFG collection system which is
necessary to collect and destroy or beneficially use the methane gas that is generated. (However,
many landfills install gas collection and control systems as the landfill is being filled, or as areas
within the landfill reach final grade, rather than waiting until closure to begin gas collection
system installation.) The costs associated with an LFG collection and flare system are minimal as
compared to the capital costs for landfill construction, annual landfill operating costs, and other
closure costs. Section 2.6 discusses average  installation costs for gas collection systems and
flares.
       Post-closure care requires maintenance to ensure the integrity and effectiveness of the
final cover system, leachate collection system, groundwater monitoring system, and methane gas
monitoring system. These activities prevent  water and air pollution from escaping into the
surrounding environment. The required post-closure care period is 30 years from site closure,
and can be shortened or extended by the director of an approved state program as necessary to
ensure protection of human health and the environment. Over a 30-year period, post-closure care
and maintenance can cost from $64,000 to $88,000 per acre (Duffy, 2005b).
                                          2-17

-------
       Figure 2-2 shows that landfill costs peak prior to the landfill opening and again following
the landfill closing (EPA, 1997).

   Illustration of Landfill Life Cycle Outlays and Costs
                               Operating Costs
                        (Fully Reflects All Life Cycle- Outlays)
              Period of Studies.
              l.judtlll A< xjiii.-ilM n.
           Construction, and Permitting
Operating
 Period
Post-Operating Period
  For Closure and
 Posr-Closure C*re
Figure 2-2  Landfill Cost Life Cycle

2.4.2  Landfill Revenue Sources

       The cost to dispose of MSW at a landfill is commonly known as a "tip fee" or "gate fee".
Typically, reported tip fees represent the "spot market" price for MSW disposal, i.e., the drive-up
cost to dispose of a ton of waste (NW&RA, 2011). Other tip fees exist at MSW facilities (e.g.,
waste accepted under a long-term contract, volume discounts, and special wastes); these fees
may be higher or lower than the spot market price (Repa, 2005). In 2012, the average national
spot market price to dispose of one ton of waste in a U.S. landfill was roughly $45, up 3.5
percent over 2011 (WBJ, 2012b), while the national  average for only the largest public and
private landfills was about $49 per ton (Kleanlndustries, 2012). This compares to average
national tip fees of approximately $32 in 1998 (Repa, 2005) and $8 in 1985 (NW&RA, 2011).
                                           2-18

-------
       Average tip fees also vary by region of the country, as shown in Table 2-5. Tip fees in
northeastern states have historically been and continue to be higher than those in other regions.
The next most expensive areas, on average, are the Mid-Atlantic and western states. Tip fees
tend to be higher near large population centers (Wright, 2012); this is likely influenced by the
fact that metropolitan areas have less land area for waste disposal and therefore, fewer landfills.
There is variation in tip fees within states as well, depending on landfill ownership (public or
private) and proximity of other landfills.

Table 2-5  Average Regional and National Per-Ton Tip Fees (Rounded): 1995-2011
U.S. Region
Northeast
Mid-Atlantic
South
Midwest
South Central
West Central
West
National
1995a
$73
$46
$29
$31
$20
$23
$38
$32
1998a
$67
$44
$31
$31
$21
$23
$36
$32
2000a
$70
$46
$31
$33
$22
$22
$35
$32
2002a
$69
$45
$30
$34
$23
$23
$39
$34
2004a
$71
$46
$31
$35
$24
$24
$38
$34
2008b
$67
$56
$32
$39
$34
$39
$44
$42
2010C
NA
NA
NA
NA
NA
NA
NA
$44
2011d
$78
$65
$39
$43
$33
$35
$55
$50
                                                South Central: AZ, AR, LA, NM, OK, TX
                                                West Central: CO, KS, MT, NE, ND, SD, UT, WY
                                                West: AK, CA, HI, ID, NV, OR, WA
  Northeast: CT, ME, MA, NH, NY, RI, VT
  Mid-Atlantic: DE, MD, NJ, PA, VA, WV
  South: AL, FL, GA, KY, MS, NC, SC, TN
  Midwest: IL, IN, IA, MI, MN, MO, OH, WI
  a Source: Repa, 2005.
   Source: Data from BioCycle, 2010. Data were not available for all states. For nine states, 2006 or 2009 data
  were substituted for missing year 2008 data.
  c Source: WBJ, 2010.
   Source: Shin, 2014 (data reported from Waste & Recycling News).

       Publicly owned landfills  set tip fees based on the need to cover landfill and other waste
management-related costs, while privately owned landfills' tip fees are set based on competition
or the lack thereof (Wright, 2012). For municipalities that depend on landfill tip fees to fund
programs and services, more waste disposed in the local community-owned landfill means more
money generated to fund their solid waste systems, including non-disposal services like
recycling. Conversely, if more waste starts going to private landfills instead, less revenue is
generated for community programs. An increasing presence of private facilities that can set
                                           2-19

-------
competitive tip fees has caused some communities to reduce their own tip fees in an effort to
attract enough disposal volume to keep revenues at a sufficient level (Burgiel, 2003).
       Historically, the construction and operating costs of public MSW landfills have been
funded by tip fees, tax revenues (e.g., county/city property tax revenue that goes into a general
fund), or a combination of these. Factors influencing tip fee values have included population and
economic growth, recycling rates, operating and transportation costs, land values, and legislation.
Traditionally, 30 percent of landfills receive all revenue from tip fees, 35 percent receive all
revenue from taxes, and 35  percent cover the costs of waste disposal through a combination of
tip fees and taxes. The use of taxes  as a revenue source rather than tip fees has implications on
waste disposal services. When disposal costs are included in taxes, most people are not aware of
the actual costs involved and there is little incentive to reduce waste generation rates. Also,
tax-supported facilities are typically underfunded relative to actual disposal costs, resulting in
poorer operation than fully funded landfills supported by tip fees. Factors that influence the
choice of revenue sources include landfill size and ownership. Landfills receiving small
quantities of waste are likely to rely heavily on taxes for their revenue while larger landfills rely
on both taxes and tip fees (EPA, 2002a).
       Private owners of landfills rely heavily on tip fees relative to other landfill owners. It
remains unclear whether private landfills rely on tip fees because they are larger,  or larger
landfills rely heavily on tip  fees because they are private (EPA, 2002a).
       As shown in Table 2-5, average tip fees by region remained fairly steady between 1995
and 2004, with minor declines in some years but with a gradual upward trend. The greatest
increases in average tip fees occurred between 1985 and 1995, with the national average tip fee
increasing by $24 (300 percent) or an average of $2.40 per year.  From 1985 to 2008, tipping fees
for private landfills increased an average of $1.25 per year but these private fees increased by
about $1.95 per year between 2004 and 2008 (Kleanlndustries, 2012). Tip fees are expected to
continue to increase gradually, based on recent data and given rising fuel costs, insurance costs,
and other operating costs (Wright, 2012).
       A landfill can also generate  revenue by entering an agreement to sell carbon credits for
voluntary destruction of methane, entering a gas sales agreement to sell LFG for beneficial use,
or entering a power purchase agreement to sell electricity generated from LFG and/or renewable
energy credits from the generation of that electricity. These types of revenue are small relative to
                                          2-20

-------
tip fees and total landfill revenues, but can help offset some landfill expenses, for example, the
cost of installing a gas collection system or energy recovery equipment. More information about
these potential revenue sources is available in Section 2.6.

2.5  Air Pollutant Emissions from Landfills

      MSW landfills are a source of NMOC which include volatile organic compounds (VOC),
methane, a potent greenhouse gas (GHG), and hazardous air pollutants. LFG is formed during
the decomposition of landfilled waste and, if not controlled, can emit numerous pollutants into
the air. Several factors affect the  amount of LFG generated and its components, including the age
and composition of the waste, the amount of organic compounds in the waste, and the moisture
content and temperature of the waste (EPA, 2012h). LFG generated from established waste
(waste that has been in place for at least a year) is  typically composed of roughly 50 percent
methane and 50 percent carbon dioxide by volume, with trace amounts of NMOC and inorganic
compounds (e.g., hydrogen sulfide) (EPA, 2015a;  EPA, 2012h).

2.5.1  NMOC in LFG

      The NMOC portion of LFG,  while a small amount of LFG by volume, can contain a
variety of significant air pollutants. NMOC include various organic hazardous air pollutants
(HAPs) and VOC. If left uncontrolled, VOC can contribute to the formation of ground-level
ozone, a common pollutant with  adverse health impacts. Nearly 30 organic hazardous air
pollutants have been identified in uncontrolled LFG, including benzene, toluene, ethyl benzene,
and vinyl chloride (EPA, 2012h).
      NMOC in LFG results mainly from the volatilization of organic compounds contained in
the landfilled waste, while some NMOC may be formed by biological processes and chemical
reactions within the waste (EPA, 1998). Waste materials that contribute to the formation of
NMOC include items such as household cleaning  products and materials coated with or
containing paints and adhesives;  during decomposition, NMOC can be stripped from these
materials by other gases (e.g., methane or carbon dioxide) and become part of the LFG (EPA,
2012h).
                                         2-21

-------
       The concentration of NMOC in uncontrolled LFG depends on several factors, including
waste types in the landfill and the local climate. EPA's Compilation of Air Pollutant Emission
Factors (AP-42) provides a default NMOC concentration of 595 parts per million by volume
(ppmv), of which 110 ppmv are considered HAP compounds. The total uncontrolled organic
HAPs volume in LFG from MSW landfills is typically less than 0.02 percent of the total LFG
(EPA, 2012h).

2.5.2   Methane in LFG

       Methane is 28-36 times more effective at retaining heat in the earth's atmosphere than
carbon dioxide, over a 100 year time horizon, and therefore is considered a potent GHG (TPCC,
2013).n In 2012, landfills were the third-largest anthropogenic source of methane emissions in
the United States, with MSW landfills accounting for approximately 15 percent of the total
methane emissions from all sources (EPA, 2015h).
       When waste is first placed in a landfill,  it enters an aerobic decomposition stage. The
availability of oxygen at this stage means that carbon released from the decomposition of organic
waste materials is in the form of carbon dioxide,  and little methane is produced. However, within
a year or less, the waste environment becomes anaerobic, methane generation increases, and the
amount of carbon dioxide produced begins to level out (EPA, 2015a). Figure 2-3 presents a
sample LFG generation curve over time for a typical MSW landfill.  Significant methane
generation can continue for 10 to 60 years after initial waste placement (EPA, 2012h).
11 Note that this proposal uses a GWP value for methane of 25 for CCh equivalency calculations, consistent with the
   GHG emissions inventories and the IPCC Fourth Assessment Report.

                                          2-22

-------
s.
~c
     1,400

     1.200

     1,000

      600

      600
   £  *n
   D.
   O
   j  200
X
           H	1	1	1	1	h
                            H	1	1	1	1	1	1	1	1	1	1	<	1	h
                                                               H	1	1	1	h
                                     8
                     S    S
                                       Year
Figure 2-3  Typical LFG Generation Curve

       As methane oxides in the atmosphere, the carbon in methane is converted to carbon
dioxide. Both the carbon dioxide generated directly from aerobic decomposition in MSW
landfills and created as a result of methane oxidation in the atmosphere is deemed biogenic
because the carbon dioxide would have been generated anyway as a result of natural
decomposition of the organic waste materials if they had not been deposited in the landfill (EPA,
2015a). In other words, the increase in atmospheric carbon dioxide concentration associated with
the decomposition of organic waste materials would have occurred in the baseline and is not
affected by the proposed rule.

2.5.3   Criteria Pollutants from Combustion of LFG

       While collection and combustion of LFG in a flare or energy project equipment (e.g.,
reciprocating engine, boiler, turbine) greatly reduces emissions of methane and NMOC
(including VOC and organic HAP), the combustion process  generates criteria pollutants
including carbon monoxide (CO), nitrogen oxides (NOx), sulfur dioxide (SCh), and particulate
                                          2-23

-------
matter (PM) (EPA, 1998). NOx formation is strongly tied to the combustion temperature in the
equipment, while CO and PM emissions are primarily the result of incomplete combustion of the
gas. 862 production depends upon the amount of sulfur in the LFG (EPA, 2000). More
information about LFG combustion devices is available in Section 2.6.

2.6   Techniques for Controlling Emissions from Landfills

2.6.1  Introduction

      Emissions from landfills can be controlled by installing gas collection systems and either
flaring the LFG or utilizing it as an energy source. Large  landfills with emissions exceeding 50
megagrams per year (Mg/yr) of NMOC are required by the MSW landfills EG to control and/or
treat LFG to significantly reduce the amount of toxic air pollutants released. However, many
landfills voluntarily choose to control emissions, in part because of the economic benefits of
LFG energy projects.
      This section describes the equipment and costs associated with LFG emission controls.
The control technologies are divided into three categories: gas collection systems, destruction,
and utilization. Much of the information in this section was obtained from the U.S. EPA's
Landfill Methane Outreach Program (LMOP) LFG Energy Project Development Handbook
(EPA, 2015a).

2.6.2  Gas Collection Systems

      LFG collection typically begins after a portion of the landfill (known as a "cell") is
closed to additional waste placement. Gas vents are installed to collect LFG from the closed cell.
The gas vents may be configured as vertical or horizontal wells, and some collection systems
involve a combination of the two. Vertical wells (Figure 2-4) are the most common method of
LFG collection and involve  drilling wells vertically in the waste to collect gas. Horizontal wells
(Figure 2-5) use piping laid  horizontally in trenches in the waste; these systems are useful in
deeper landfills and in areas of active filling. Both types of collection systems connect the
wellheads to lateral piping that transports the gas to a collection header.
                                          2-24

-------
               WASTE
               COVER
    WELLHE/i

     SOLID
     PIPE
                   SOIL BACKFILL


              BENTONITE PLUG
                PERFORATED PIPE
                 GRAVEL PACK

                    BORE HOLE
                           Source: EPA, 2015a
                Figure 2-4 Vertical Well LFG Collection
                                                      WELLHEAD
          WASTE COVER

              GEOTEXTILE
PERFORATED PIPE
     GRAVEL PACK
BENTONITE PLUG
                           Source: EPA, 2015a
              Figure 2-5 Horizontal Well LFG Collection
                                2-25

-------
       Collection from the gas vents may be either passive or active. Passive systems rely on the
natural pressure gradient between the waste mass and the atmosphere to move gas to collection
systems. Most passive systems intercept LFG migration and the collected gas is vented to the
atmosphere. Active systems use mechanical blowers or compressors to create a vacuum that
optimizes LFG collection (EPA, 1998).
       Collection efficiency is a measure of the ability of a gas collection system to capture
generated LFG. Although rates of LFG capture can be measured, rates of actual generation in a
landfill cannot be measured; therefore, considerable uncertainty exists regarding actual collection
efficiencies achieved at landfills. Collection efficiencies at landfills with comprehensive gas
collection systems typically range from 50 to 95 percent, with an average of 75 percent most
commonly assumed (EPA, 1998;  Sullivan, 2010; EPA, 2015a). In the current GHGRP
requirements for MSW landfills (40 CFR part 98, subpart HH), LFG collection efficiencies vary
for active gas collection systems depending upon cover material type, with daily soil cover
assigned 60 percent, intermediate/final soil cover assigned 75 percent (also the default value),
and final  soil cover of three feet or thicker of clay and/or geomembrane cover system assigned
95 percent.
       Total collection system costs vary widely, based on a number of site-specific factors. For
example, if the landfill is deep, collection costs tend to be higher because well depths will need
to be increased. Collection costs also increase with the number of wells installed. Based on data
from LMOP's Landfill Gas Energy Cost Model (LFGcost-Web), the estimated capital cost (in
2012 $'s) required for a 40-acre collection system is $897,000, assuming one well is installed per
acre. Typical annual operation and maintenance (O&M) costs (in 2012 $'s) for collection
systems are approximately $2,500 per well, or $100,000 for a 40-acre system (EPA, 2014b). If
an LFG energy project generates electricity, a landfill will often use a portion of the electricity
generated to operate the system and sell the rest to the grid in order to offset these operational
costs.

2.6.3   Destruction

       Collected LFG is typically combusted in flares or combustion devices that recover
energy, such as boilers, internal combustion engines, and gas turbines. Properly designed and
operated combustion equipment generally reduces NMOC by 98 percent or to a 20 ppmv outlet
                                          2-26

-------
concentration, as specified in the current MSW landfills EG (40 CFR 60.752). Combustion also
destroys over 98 percent of the methane.
       Flares are the most common control device used at landfills. Flares are also a component
of each energy recovery option because they may be needed to control LFG emissions during
energy recovery system startup and downtime and to control any gas that exceeds the capacity of
the energy conversion equipment. In addition, a flare is a cost-effective way to gradually increase
the size of the energy recovery system at an active landfill. As more waste is placed in the
landfill and the gas collection system is expanded, the flare is used to control excess gas between
energy conversion system upgrades (e.g., before addition of another engine).
       Flare designs include open (or candlestick) flares and enclosed flares. Open flares employ
simple technology where the collected gas is combusted in an elevated open burner. A
continuous or intermittent pilot light is generally used to maintain the combustion. Open flares
used at landfills meeting the criteria in 40 CFR 60.18(b) have been demonstrated to have
destruction efficiencies similar to enclosed flares. Enclosed flares typically employ multiple
burners within fire-resistant walls, which allow them to maintain a relatively constant and limited
peak temperature by regulating the supply of combustion air (ATSDR, 2001). Enclosed flares are
more expensive but may be preferable (or required by state regulations) because they provide
greater control of combustion conditions and allow for stack testing. They can also reduce noise
and light nuisances.
       Flare costs vary based on the gas flow of the system. LFGcost-Web estimates for flares
include condensate collection and blowers. Condensate collection (also called knockout devices)
is necessary because condensate forms when warm gas from the landfill cools as it travels
through the collection system. If condensate is not removed, it can block the collection system.
Blowers are needed to ensure a steady flow of gas to the flare. The size, type, and number of
blowers needed depend on the gas flow rate and distance to downstream processes.
       Based on data from LFGcost-Web (in 2012$), a flare for a system  designed for 600 cubic
feet per minute (cfm) of LFG will cost $223,000 (including condensate collection and blowers).
Typical annual O&M costs (in 2012$) are approximately $5,000 per flare. Electricity costs to
operate the blower for a 600-cfm active gas collection system would be $53,000 per year,
assuming an electricity price of $0.085 per kilowatt-hour (kWh) (EPA, 2014b).
                                          2-27

-------
2.6.4  Utilization

       After collection, LFG may be used in an energy recovery system to combust the methane
and other trace contaminants. LMOP's Landfill and LFG Energy Project Database, which tracks
the development of U.S. LFG energy projects and landfills with project development potential,
indicates that approximately 640 LFG energy projects are currently operating in 48 states and
Puerto Rico. Roughly three-fourths of these projects generate electricity, while one-fourth are
direct-use projects in which LFG is used for its thermal capacity (EPA, 2015b).
       This section summarizes LFG utilization technologies in four general categories: power
production, cogeneration, direct use, and alternative fuel. This section also provides a discussion
of the economic benefits of LFG utilization projects.

2.6.4.1  Technologies
       It is important to note that all of the technologies discussed below typically require
treatment of LFG prior to entering the control device to remove moisture, particulates, and other
impurities. (While "treatment" has a specific meaning within the MSW landfills EG, the term is
used more generally in common usage and as discussed here.) The level of treatment can vary
depending on the type of control and the types and amounts of contaminants in the gas. LFG is
typically dehumidified, filtered, and compressed before being sent to energy recovery devices.
For most boilers  and internal combustion engines, no additional treatment is used. Some internal
combustion engines and many gas turbine and microturbine projects apply siloxane removal
using adsorption beds after the dehumidification step.

2.6.4.1.1 Power Production
       Producing electricity from LFG continues to be the most common beneficial-use
application, accounting for about three-fourths of all U.S.  LFG energy projects (EPA, 2015b).
Electricity can be produced by burning LFG in an internal combustion engine, a gas turbine, or a
microturbine.
       The majority (more than 70 percent) of LFG energy projects that generate electricity do
so by combusting LFG in internal combustion engines. Advantages of this technology include:
low capital cost,  high efficiency, and adaptability to variations in the gas output of landfills.
Internal combustion engines are well-suited for 800-kilowatt (kW) to 3-megawatt (MW)
                                          2-28

-------
projects, but multiple units can be used together for projects larger than 3 MW. Internal
combustion engines are relatively efficient at converting LFG into electricity, achieving
efficiencies in the range of 25 to 35 percent.
       Gas turbines are more likely to be used for large projects, where LFG volumes are
sufficient to generate a minimum of 3 MW and typically more than 5 MW. Unlike most internal
combustion engine systems, gas turbine systems have significant economies of scale. The cost
per kW of generating capacity drops as gas turbine size increases, and the electric generation
efficiency generally improves as well.
       Microturbines, as their name suggests, are much smaller than turbines, with a single unit
having between 30 and 250 kW in capacity, and thus are generally used for projects smaller than
1 MW. Small internal combustion engines are also available for projects in this size range and
are generally less costly. Microturbines may be selected for certain projects (rather than internal
combustion engines) because they can operate with as little as 35 percent methane and less than
300 cfm, and also produce low nitrogen oxide emissions.
       An  LFG energy project may use multiple units to accommodate a landfill's specific gas
flow over time. For example, a project might have three internal combustion engines, two gas
turbines, or an array of 10 microturbines, depending on gas flow and energy needs.
       The costs of energy generation using LFG vary greatly; they depend on many factors
including the type and size of electricity generation equipment, the necessary compression and
treatment system, and the interconnect equipment. Table 2-6 presents examples of typical costs
for several  technologies, including costs for a basic gas treatment system typically used with
each technology as well as interconnection costs.
Table 2-6  Average LFG Power Production Technology Costs
Technology
Internal combustion engine
Small internal combustion engine
Gas turbine
Microturbine
Typical Size Used
to Estimate Costs
3,000 kW
500 kW
10,000 kW
200 kW
Typical Capital
Costs ($/kW)a
$1,700
$2,500
$1,400
$2,900
Typical Annual O&M
Costs ($/kW)a
$200
$220
$130
$220
Source: EPA, 2014b
a2012$
                                          2-29

-------
2.6.4.1.2  Cogeneration
       LFG energy cogeneration applications, also known as combined heat and power (CHP)
projects, provide greater overall energy efficiency and are growing in number. In addition to
producing electricity, these projects recover and beneficially use the heat from the unit
combusting LFG. LFG cogeneration projects can use internal combustion engine, gas turbine, or
microturbine technologies.
       Less common LFG electricity generation technologies include a few boiler/steam turbine
applications in which LFG is combusted in a large boiler to generate steam which is then used by
a steam turbine to create electricity. A few combined cycle applications have also been
implemented. These combine a gas turbine that combusts LFG with a steam turbine that uses
steam generated from the gas turbine's exhaust to create electricity. Boiler/steam turbine and
combined cycle applications tend to be larger in scale than the majority of LFG electricity
projects that use internal combustion engines.

2.6.4.1.3  Direct Use
       The simplest and often most cost-effective use of LFG is direct use as a fuel for boilers
and other direct thermal applications to produce useful heat or steam. However, this is only an
option if there is  an end user located near the landfill who is willing and able to use the LFG. An
end user's energy requirements are an important consideration when evaluating the sale of LFG
for direct use. Because no economical way to store LFG exists,  all gas that is recovered must be
used as available; gas that cannot be immediately used in energy recovery equipment is flared
and the associated revenue opportunities are lost. The ideal gas  customer, therefore, will have a
steady annual gas demand compatible with the landfill's gas flow. When a landfill does not have
adequate gas flow to support the entire needs of a facility, LFG can still be used to supply a
portion of the needs. The number and diversity of direct-use LFG applications is continuing to
grow.
       Boilers are the most common type of direct use, and LFG is used in boilers at a wide
variety of industrial manufacturing facilities as well as commercial and institutional buildings.
Boilers can often be easily converted to use LFG alone or in combination with fossil fuels.
Equipment modifications or adjustments may be necessary to accommodate the lower Btu value
of LFG, and the costs of modifications will vary. If retuning the boiler burner is the only
                                          2-30

-------
modification required, costs will be minimal. However, retrofitting an existing natural gas boiler
to include LFG may cost between $100,000 and $400,000, depending on the extent of the retrofit
(EPA, 2014b).
       Direct thermal applications include kilns (e.g., cement, pottery, and brick), tunnel
furnaces, process heaters, and blacksmithing forges. In addition, infrared heaters can use LFG to
fulfill space heating needs. Greenhouses can combust LFG in boilers to provide heat for the
greenhouse and to heat water used in hydroponic plant culture. LFG can be used to heat the
boilers in plants that produce biofuels including biodiesel and ethanol.
       Table 2-7 presents typical cost ranges for the components of a direct-use project. The
costs shown below for the gas compression and treatment system include compression, moisture
removal, and filtration equipment typically required to prepare the gas for transport through the
pipeline and for use in a boiler or process heater. If more extensive treatment is required to
remove other impurities, costs will be higher. The gas pipeline costs also assume typical
construction conditions and pipeline design. Pipelines can range from less than a mile to more
than 30 miles long, although most are shorter than  10 miles because length has a major effect on
costs. In addition, the costs of direct-use pipelines are often affected by  obstacles along the route,
such as highway, railroad, or water crossings. End users will likely need to modify their
equipment to make it suitable for combusting LFG, but these costs are usually borne by the end
user and are site-specific to their combustion device.
Table 2-7  Average LFG Direct-use Project Components Costs
Component
Gas compression and treatment
Gas pipeline and condensate
management system
Typical Capital Costs"
$l,200/cfm
$449,000/mile
Typical Annual O&M Costsa'b
$130/cfm
Negligible
Source: EPA, 2014b
a 2012$, based on a 1,000-cfm system with a 5-mile pipeline
cfm: cubic feet per minute
b Assuming an electricity price of $0.085 per kWh
2.6.4.1.4 Alternative Fuel
       Production of alternative fuels from LFG, by upgrading the gas using high-Btu
conversion technologies, is becoming more prevalent. LFG can be used to produce the
                                          2-31

-------
equivalent of pipeline-quality gas (natural gas), compressed natural gas (CNG), or liquefied
natural gas (LNG). Pipeline-quality gas can be injected into a natural gas pipeline and used by
residential, commercial, or industrial end users along the pipeline. CNG and LNG can be used to
fuel vehicles at the landfill (e.g., water trucks, earthmoving equipment, light trucks, autos), fuel
refuse-hauling tucks (long-haul refuse transfer trailers and route collection trucks), and supply
the general commercial market. Although only a handful of these projects are currently
operational, several more are in the construction or planning stages.
       LFG can be converted into a high-Btu gas by increasing its methane content and,
conversely, reducing its carbon dioxide, nitrogen, and oxygen content. In the United States, three
methods have been commercially employed (i.e., beyond pilot testing) to remove carbon dioxide
from LFG, including membrane separation, molecular sieve (also known as pressure swing
adsorption or PSA), and amine scrubbing.
       Capital costs of high-Btu processing equipment (in 2012$) range from $2,500 per cfm
LFG for a 10,000-cfm processing system to $5,900 per cfm LFG for a 1,000-cfm processing
system. The annual cost to provide electricity to, operate, and maintain these systems (in 2012$)
is approximately $500 per cfm LFG (EPA, 2014b). Costs will depend on the purity of the high-
Btu gas required by the receiving pipeline or energy end user as well as the size of the project,
since some economies of scale can be achieved when producing larger quantities of high-Btu
gas.
       For alternative fuel projects, the capital costs of converting LFG into CNG also vary,
depending primarily on the quantity of fuel being converted and the type of fueling station
equipment. Similar to high-Btu processing equipment, some economies of scale are realized for
larger volumes of gas. The capital costs for onsite CNG production with a fueling station (in
2012$) ranges from $7,200 per cfm LFG for a 600-cfm project to $14,800 per cfm LFG for a
100-cfm project. The annual cost to operate and maintain a CNG project (in 2012$), including
media and equipment replacement, is approximately $1 per gallon of gasoline equivalent
produced by the system, or $0.003 per cfm LFG assuming  a conversion efficiency of 65 percent
and a fuel use rate of 111,200 Btu per gallon of gasoline equivalent (EPA, 2014b).
                                          2-32

-------
2.6.4.2  Revenues and Incentives
       Landfill owners can receive revenue from the sale of carbon credits, the sale of electricity
generated from LFG to the local power grid, or from the sale of LFG to a direct end user or
pipeline. However, the revenue received represents only a small percentage of the operating
costs of a landfill.

2.6.4.2.1 GHG Credits
       Voluntary GHG trading programs purchase credits from landfills that capture LFG to
destroy or convert methane contained in the gas and obtain credit for the reduction of GHG in
terms of carbon equivalents. In order to qualify for these programs, the emission reductions must
be in addition to regulated actions and have recent project installation. Examples of companies
operating on the voluntary carbon market include Climate Action Reserve, EcoSecurities,
Evolution Markets, Blue Source, and Chicago Climate Exchange (EPA 2012a).
       Bilateral trading and GHG credit sales are other voluntary sources of revenue. Bilateral
trades are project-specific and are negotiated directly between a buyer and seller of GHG credits.
In these cases, corporate entities or public institutions, such as universities, may wish to reduce
their "carbon footprint" or meet internal sustainability goals, but  do not have direct access to
developing their own project. Therefore, a buyer may help finance a specific project in exchange
for the credit of offsetting GHG emissions from their organization.
       Many state and regional government entities are establishing their own GHG initiatives to
cap or minimize GHG emissions within their jurisdictions. Examples include the Regional
Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI), the Washington carbon dioxide offset program, and
Massachusetts' carbon dioxide reduction from new plants. Some of these programs establish a
cap-and-trade program on carbon dioxide emissions, while others require new fossil-fueled
boilers and power plants to  either implement or contribute to funding of offset projects, including
LFG.
       Certain LFG energy projects may qualify for participation in nitrogen oxides cap-and-
trade programs, such as the nitrogen oxides State Implementation Plan (SIP). The revenues for
these incentives vary by state and will  depend on factors such as  the allowances allocated to each
project, the price of allowances on the market, and if the project is a CHP project (typically CHP
projects receive more revenue due to credit for avoided boiler fuel use).
                                          2-33

-------
2.6.4.2.2  Electricity Project Revenue
       The primary revenue component of the typical electricity project is the sale of electricity
to the local utility. This revenue stream is affected by the electricity buy-back rates (i.e., the rate
at which the local utility purchases electricity generated by the LFG energy project). Electricity
buy-back rates for new projects depend on several factors specific to the local electric utility and
the type of contract available to the project, but typically range between 2.5 and 11 cents per
kWh(EPA, 2014b).
       When assessing the economics of an electricity project, it is also important to consider
the avoided cost of the electricity used on site. Electricity generated by the project that is used in
other operations at the landfill is, in effect, electricity that the landfill does not have to purchase
from a utility. This electricity is not valued at the buy-back rate, but at the rate the landfill is
charged to purchase electricity (i.e., retail rate). The retail rate is often significantly higher than
the buy-back rate.
       LFG energy projects can potentially use a variety of additional environmental revenue
streams, which typically take advantage of the fact that LFG is recognized as a renewable, or
"green," energy resource. These additional revenues can come from premium pricing, tax credits,
GHG credit trading, or incentive payments. They can be reflected in an economic analysis in
various ways, but typically, converting to a cents/kWh format is most useful. LFGcost-Web
accommodates four common types of electricity project credits: a direct cash grant, an electricity
generation tax credit expressed in dollars per kWh, a direct GHG (carbon) reduction credit
expressed in dollars per metric ton  of carbon dioxide equivalent (discussed in Section 2.6.4.2.1),
and a direct renewable electricity credit expressed in dollars per kWh. This section includes
discussion of the available environmental revenue streams that an LFG electricity project could
possibly use.
       Premium pricing is often available  for renewable electricity (including LFG) that is
included in a green power program, through a Renewable Portfolio Standard (RPS), a Renewable
Portfolio Goal (RPG), or a voluntary  utility green pricing program. These programs could
provide additional revenue above the standard buy-back rate because LFG electricity is
generated from a renewable resource.
       Renewable energy certificates (RECs) are sold through voluntary markets to consumers
seeking to reduce their environmental footprint. They are typically offered in 1 megawatt-hour
                                           2-34

-------
(MWh) units, and are sold by LFG electricity generators to industries, commercial businesses,
institutions, and even private citizens who wish to achieve a corporate renewable energy
portfolio goal or to encourage renewable energy. If the electricity produced by an LFG energy
project is not being sold as part of a utility green power program or green pricing program, the
project owner may be able to sell RECs through voluntary markets to generate additional
revenue.
       Tax credits, tax exemptions, and other tax incentives, as well as federal and state grants,
low-cost bonds, and loan programs are available to potentially provide funding for an LFG
energy project. For example, Section 45 of the Internal Revenue Code provides a per-kWh
federal tax credit, commonly referred to as the renewable electricity Production Tax Credit
(PTC), for power generated at privately owned LFG electricity projects. To qualify for the credit,
which was 1.1 cent per kWh for the 2014 calendar year, all electricity produced must be sold to
an unrelated person during the taxable year. Under legislation passed in December 2014, the
placed-in-service date deadline for LFG energy projects to be eligible was extended to December
31, 2014 (DSIRE, 2015).

2.6.4.2.3 Direct-use Project Revenues
       The primary source of revenue for direct-use projects is the sale of LFG to the end user;
the price of LFG, therefore, dictates a project's revenue. Often LFG sales prices are indexed to
the price of natural gas, but prices will vary depending on site-specific negotiations, the type of
contract, and other factors. In recent years, typical LFG prices have ranged from $1.50 to $4.00
per million British thermal units (MMBtu) or 0.140 to 0.380 per megajoule (EPA, 2013). In
general, the price paid by the end user must provide an energy cost savings that outweighs the
cost of required modifications to boilers, process heaters, kilns, and furnaces in order to burn
LFG.

       Federal and state tax incentives, loans, and grants are available that may provide
additional revenue for direct-use projects. Specific to vehicle fuel, EPA's Renewable Fuel
Standard (RFS) program allows registered renewable fuel producers,  including biofuels
produced from LFG, to generate Renewable Identification Number (RIN) credits for the
renewable fuel produced which are purchased by parties required to meet specified volumes of
renewable fuel (EPA, 2014d). In 2014, RIN credits for advanced biofuels (such as LFG-based
                                          2-35

-------
biogas) were between $0.74 and $1.00 per RIN, equivalent to a range of $9 to $13 per million
Btu (ABC, 2014). GHG emissions trading programs are also potential revenue streams for direct-
use projects.

2.7  Integrated Waste Management Strategies

2.7.1   Introduction

       Landfills are one method of waste disposal, but alternative strategies are available for the
treatment of MSW, and multiple strategies are often used in combination. EPA has developed a
non-hazardous waste management hierarchy that ranks the most environmentally sound
strategies for MSW. Source reduction and reuse (waste prevention) is the most preferred method,
followed by recycling and composting, energy recovery, and, lastly, treatment and disposal
(EPA, 2015c).
       Waste prevention is the practice of designing products to reduce the amount of waste that
will later need to be thrown  away, which may result in less toxic waste (EPA, 2015d). Recycling
involves the recovery of useful materials, such as paper, glass, plastic, and metals from trash and
using these materials to make new products. Recycling saves resources, including energy, raw
materials, and landfill space.
       The diversion of organic materials, such as food scraps and yard waste (e.g., lawn
trimmings, fallen leaves and branches), from landfills allows these materials to be used to create
compost or generate energy. The management of organic materials is discussed in Section 2.7.2.
       Alternatively, MSW can be directly combusted in waste-to-energy facilities to generate
electricity. At the power plant, MSW is unloaded from collection trucks and shredded or
processed to ease handling. Recyclable materials are separated out, and the remaining waste is
fed into a combustion chamber to be burned. The heat released from burning the MSW is used to
produce steam, which turns  a steam turbine to generate electricity (EPA, 2015e).
       Landfilling is often used as part of an integrated waste management strategy (e.g., where
the same community has recycling programs, yard waste composting, and landfilling) and LFG
can often be used for energy recovery as described in Section 2.6.4. LFG energy projects aim to
recover and beneficially utilize methane generated from waste that has not been successfully
diverted from landfills.  The  promotion of LFG energy is not in conflict with the promotion of
                                          2-36

-------
organic waste diversion, nor does it compete with waste prevention or recycling, but allows LFG
energy projects to utilize methane generated from millions of tons of organic waste already
disposed in landfills while supporting future diversion of organic waste from landfills to reduce
the amount of uncontrolled methane generated. In addition, some studies have shown that
diverting waste from landfills may not always result in a comparative reduction in GHG
emissions when efficient LFG collection systems and lifecycle emissions (from transportation
and processing of organic waste) are taken into account (EPA, 2015 f).

2.7.2   Organics Management

       As detailed in Section 2.2.1.4, food waste, yard debris, and other organic materials
continue to be the largest component of MSW discarded, with food waste comprising the largest
portion (EPA, 2014a). Decreasing the amount of organics disposed in landfills would reduce the
amount of LFG generated. If diverted from  disposal in landfills, organic wastes can be
composted or anaerobically digested.
       Composting is the controlled biological decomposition of organic material in the
presence of air to form a humus-like material. Controlled methods  of composting include
mechanical mixing and aerating, ventilating the materials by dropping them through a vertical
series of aerated chambers, or placing the compost in piles out in the open air and mixing the
piles periodically (EPA, 2015g). Diverted organic materials can also be used in an anaerobic
digester, although digesters generally handle relatively small quantities of easily digestible
waste. BioCycle identified nearly 5,000 composting facilities in the United States, with about 70
percent composting only yard trimmings and 7 percent composting food scraps (BioCycle,
2014a).
       Anaerobic digestion involves the conversion of organic matter to energy by
microbiological organisms in the absence of oxygen. The biogas produced in the digestion
process is a mixture of methane and carbon dioxide and can be used as a fuel source for heating
or electricity production. Organic waste can either be digested at facilities specifically designed
for the organic portion of MSW, or co-digested at wastewater treatment plants and manure
digesters. The number of anaerobic digesters in the United States that process MSW-based
wastes is on the rise from the first commercial scale plant coming online by 2010 up to more
than seven plants operating by 2013, some of them  digesting food waste alone and others co-
                                          2-37

-------
digesting food waste with wastewater and other organics (Arsova, 2010; RWI, 2013a; RWI,
2013b).

2.7.2.1  Trends
       States and municipalities in the United States are increasingly moving toward the
diversion of organic wastes from landfills. State initiatives to recycle organic wastes have
contributed to the growth of curbside organics collection as well as commercial and institutional
collection and treatment. Table 2-8 lists the 21 states that have mandated organics diversion
and/or banned disposal of organics from landfills. In particular, five states (California,
Connecticut, Massachusetts, Rhode Island, and Vermont) have enacted legislation for organics
disposal specific to food waste (BioCycle, 2014b; MSW Management, 2015). At a local level,
BioCycle's Fall 2014 survey identified 198 communities in 19 states with curbside collection of
food scraps, as shown in Table 2-8. Between 2009 and 2014, the number of municipalities with
source separated food waste collection more than doubled (from 90 to 198) and the number of
households grew by nearly 50 percent (BioCycle, 2015). The assortment of organics
management initiatives and programs at state and local levels varies across the country by:
       •  Type of organic wastes targeted (e.g., food waste, yard waste);
       •  Source of organic waste generation (e.g., commercial, residential, institutional);
       •  Phase of implementation (from pilot projects to mandatory requirements with fines
          for violations); and
       •  Pricing formats (e.g., "pay-as-you-throw," property tax, fixed fee) (BioCycle, 2015).
                                          2-38

-------
Table 2-8  Waste Management of Organics in the United States
 State
                               State-wide Organics
                            Diversion Mandate and/or
                            	Disposal Ban1'2'3	
 Local Residential Food
    Waste Collection
	Program4	
 Arkansas
 California
 Colorado
 Connecticut
 Delaware
 Illinois
 India
 Iowa
 Kentucky
 Maryland
        hu
 Michigan
      ssota
 Nebraska
 New Hampshire
 New Jersey
 New York
 North Carolina
 Oregon
 Rhode Island
 Pennsylvania
 South Carolina
 South Dakota
 Tennessee
 Texas
 Vermont
 Washington
   isconsin
 Number of States
W:
                                                                 19
FW = Food waste diversion mandate and/or disposal ban
1 Source: BioCycle, 2014a. Survey results from 39 states that responded.
2 Source: BioCycle, 2014b. Rhode Island legislation goes into effect January 2016.
3 Source: MSW Management, 2015.
4 Source: BioCycle, 2015. Denotes states that have one or more communities with a residential source separated
food waste collection program. Programs are not state-wide initiatives.
                                                2-39

-------
2.7.2.2  Benefits
       The benefits of diverting organic wastes from landfills include:
       •  Reduction of methane, NMOC, and other air pollutants generated by the organic
          fraction of waste disposed in landfills;
       •  Production of soil-improving compost material from composting (TLSR, 2014);
       •  Generation of biogas from anaerobic digestion used to generate electricity and/or
          heat; and
       •  Recovery and recycling of food waste to support food banks for humans or animals
          (MSW Management, 2015).

2.7.2.3  Barriers
       Some barriers exist that can deter mandating the diversion of organics from landfills,
       especially in the format of a federal mandate, such as:
       •  Lack of or variation in regulatory policies, incentives, and drivers to encourage
          organics diversion and make it more affordable (TLSR, 2014). For example,
          Kentucky's composting permit fees for private entities led to a decline in applicants
          when the fee went from $0 to $3,000 in 2011, with an annual renewal fee of $500
          (BioCycle, 2014b). While New York does not have legislation in place, the state does
          review local materials management plans to provide suggestions on improving
          organics management and offers waste reduction and recycling grants to
          municipalities for education or capital expenditures (BioCycle, 2014b). Lessening
          permit restrictions and fees for organic waste facilities and offering state-level
          assistance to municipalities may spur movement to establish and expand organics
          management programs.
       •  Limited capacity for organic material receiving, processing, and treatment facilities
          (e.g., composters, anaerobic digesters) and associated infrastructure (e.g., hauling
          services, transfer stations) (ILSR, 2014). While the United States has no shortage of
          landfill capacity overall, the average amount of organics diverted to composting in 27
          states is 5,155 tons per facility per year, which is far too low to adequately achieve
          higher composting rates (BioCycle, 2014a). Composting of organics can occur at
          several tiers, from home-based and small-scale farm and community sites to onsite
                                          2-40

-------
institutional systems (primarily schools) to large-scale centralized facilities, thus
encouraging backyard and locally-based composting and developing adequate
infrastructure for commercial composting (beyond yard waste) would lead to an
increased capacity for organic wastes in urban, suburban, and rural areas (BioCycle,
2014a).
Low cost to dispose waste in landfills relative to other waste treatment technologies
(ILSR, 2014). Traditionally, waste disposal in the United States has been based on
landfill tipping fees, or the fee a waste collector or hauler pays  to discard waste in a
landfill. Tipping fees at landfills vary across the United States,  ranging from $5 to
$142 per ton in 2011, with a national average just below $50 per ton (Shin, 2014).
When recycling and organics diversion are introduced, the pricing structure shifts
from a disposal cost to transportation and processing or treatment costs. Anaerobic
digesters require significant capital investment and rely on tipping fees to recover
costs to construct and operate the facility.  In addition,  due to opposition for siting
these facilities, it is difficult to obtain permits to build digesters in densely populated
areas, which results in increased costs to transport feedstock to the digester
(WasteS60, 2014). More recently, local solid waste agencies have offered reduced
fees for source separated loads of organics at composting facilities. For example,
Charleston County, South Carolina has a $25 per ton fee to drop off food and organic
waste for composting, compared to $66 per ton for traditional waste sent to the
landfill (ILSR, 2014). In addition, variable rate fees, or "pay-as-you-throw" pricing,
incentivize separate collection of organics and recyclables as trash collection is
typically priced at a higher fee than source separated organics and recyclables (ILSR,
2014).
Multifaceted and regional nature of the solid waste management industry. Waste
generators include households, institutions, and commercial entities, and these parties
vary regionally in both density and demographics. Historically, state and local
government has controlled all aspects of collection, transportation, disposal, and
treatment of solid waste including the permitting of facilities and infrastructure and
assessment of fees through taxes and operation of landfills. Private companies also
play a significant role that ranges from collecting and hauling waste to owning and
                                 2-41

-------
          operating landfills. While the industry is moving towards more integrated solid waste

          management approaches at a local or regional level, there is not a shift towards a

          national solid waste management system. As a result, the policies, programs, and

          infrastructure to accommodate organics diversion must be tailored to the unique

          situations of each region, state, or municipality to best implement change among

          interlinked entities of generators, collectors, and treatment and disposal facilities.

          Lack of information and understanding of the environmental and energy benefits of

          separating, recovering, and utilizing organics. Ultimately, effective organics

          diversion from landfills begins at the point of generation. Changing waste disposal

          habits can be challenging for individuals, businesses, and industries in the United

          States, but education and awareness about the benefits of composting and anaerobic

          digestion in a manner that relates directly to individuals and organizations may

          encourage and increase diversion of organics.
2.8  References

Alva, 2010. "Successfully Permitting a Solid Waste Landfill in a Metropolitan Area: Sunshine
       Landfill Expansion Project." Paul Alva. Solid Waste Association of North America
       (SWANA) WASTECON 2010.

American Biogas Council (ABC). 2014. "A Snapshot of RNG and the Market." May 12, 2014.
       .

Arsova, Ljupka. 2010. "Anaerobic Digestion of Food Waste: Current Status, Problems and an
       Alternative Product." Columbia University. Earth Engineering Center. May 2010.
       .

ATSDR. 2001. Landfill Gas Primer - An Overview for Environmental Health Professionals,
       Chapter 5: Landfill Gas Control Measures. Agency for Toxic Substances and Disease
       Registry (ATSDR). November 2001.
       .

BioCycle. 2010. "17th Nationwide  Survey of MSW Management in the U.S.: The State of
       Garbage in America." October 2010. .

BioCycle. 2014a. "State of Composting in the U.S." July 2014.
       .

BioCycle. 2014b. "Taking States' Pulse On Residential Food Waste Collection." October 2014.
                                          2-42

-------
BioCycle. 2015. "BioCycle Nationwide Survey: Residential Food Waste Collection in the U.S."
       January 2015. . [Table found in print edition only]

Bloomberg BusinessWeek. 2014BIN. Financial Statements for Progressive Waste Solutions
       (BIN). Annual Income Statement as of December 31, 2013.
       .

Bloomberg BusinessWeek. 2014CLH. 2013 SEC Filings - Clean Harbors Inc (CLH). 10-K,
       Annual Financials, March 3, 2014.
       . Accessed February 5, 2015.

Duffy, Daniel P. 2005a. MSW Management. "Landfill Economics Part II: Getting Down to
       Business".  June 2005.
       .

Duffy, Daniel P. 2005b. MSW Management. "Landfill Economics Part III: Closing Up Shop".
       August 2005.
                                         2-43

-------
      .

EnSol, Inc. 2010. "Cortland County Landfill Alternatives Analysis". October 2010.
      .

Fitzwater, Ryan. 2012. Seeking Alpha. "The Top Three Dividend Paying Waste Management
      Stocks". May 21, 2012. .

Greenhouse Gas Reporting Program (GHGRP). 2013. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency.
      Web page: GHG Reporting Program Data Sets. Download GHGRP Data by Year. 2013
      GHG Data. Envirofacts.
      .

Guyer, 2009. "Introduction to Sanitary Landfills" J. Paul Guyer, CED Engineering. 2009.
      .

Intergovernmental Panel on Panel Climate Change, 2007. IPCC Fourth Assessment Report
      (AR4), 2007. Climate Change 2007: The Physical Science Basis. Contribution of
      Working Group I to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on
      Climate Change [Core Writing Team, Pachauri, R.K and Reisinger, A. (eds.)]. IPCC,
      Geneva, Switzerland, 104pp.

Kentucky Energy and Environment Cabinet, Department for Environmental Protection, Division
      of Waste Management, Solid Waste Branch (KY SWB). 2012. "Landfill Permitting
      Overview". Accessed December 4, 2012.
      .

Kleanlndustries. 2012. "Tipping fees vary across the U.S." July 2012.
      .

Maryland Department of the Environment (MDE). 2012. "Estimated Costs of Landfill Closure".
      Accessed December 4, 2012.
      .

MSW Management. 2015. "LFGTE Supplement: The Organic Factor." January/February 2015.
      .
                                        2-44

-------
National Waste & Recycling Association (NW&RA) (formerly National Solid Wastes
       Management Association). 2008. "Modern Landfills: A Far Cry from the Past." August
       2008. .

Renewable Waste Intelligence (RWI). 2013a. "Business Analysis of Anaerobic Digestion in the
       U.S.A." March 2013. .

Renewable Waste Intelligence (RWI). 2013b. "Commercial Updates: Municipal  Solid Waste
       Conversion on the West Coast U.S.A." October 2013.

Repa, Edward W. National Solid Wastes Management Association (NSWMA). 2005.
       "NSWMA's 2005 Tip Fee Survey." March 2005.
       .

Shin, Dolly. 2014. "Generation and Disposition of Municipal Solid Waste (MSW) in the United
       States - A National Survey." Columbia University. Earth Engineering Center. January 3,
       2014. .

Solid Waste Association of North America (SWANA). 2007. "The Regional Privately-Owned
       Landfill Trend and Its Impact on Integrated Solid Waste Management Systems."
       February 2007.

Sullivan, Patrick. 2010.  "The Importance of Landfill Gas Capture and Utilization in the U.S."
       Columbia University. Earth Engineering Center. Council for Sustainable  Use of
       Resources. April 6, 2010.
       .

U.S. Census Bureau (Census). 2012. Economic Census and Population Estimates. Economic
       Census: Industry Snapshots. Solid Waste Landfill (NAICS 562212). 2012.
       .

U.S. Census Bureau (Census). 2013. Annual Survey of Public Employment & Payroll. Local
       Government Employment and Payroll Data. March 2013.
       .
                                         2-45

-------
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 1997. "Full Cost Accounting for Municipal Solid
       Waste Management: A Handbook, Chapter 4: Allocating Costs." September 1997. EPA-
       530-R-95-041. .

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 1998. Office of Air and Radiation, Office of Air
       Quality Planning and Standards. "Compilation of Air Pollutant Emission Factors, Fifth
       Edition, Volume I: Stationary Point and Area Sources, Chapter 2: Solid Waste Disposal,
       Section 2.4: Municipal Solid Waste Landfills". November 1998.
       .

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2000. Office of Air and Radiation, Office of Air
       Quality Planning and Standards. "Compilation of Air Pollutant Emission Factors, Fifth
       Edition, Volume I: Stationary Point and Area Sources, Chapter 3: Stationary Internal
       Combustion Sources, Section 3.1: Stationary Gas Turbines". April 2000.
       .

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2002a. "Economic Impact Analysis for the
       Supplemental to the Municipal Solid Waste (MSW) NESHAP." December 2002. EPA-
       452-R-03-001.
       .

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2002b. Solid Waste and Emergency Response.
       "Waste Transfer Stations: A Manual for Decision-Making." June 2002. EPA-530-R-02-
       002. .

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2010. "Municipal Solid Waste in the United
       States: 2009 Facts and Figures." December 2010. EPA-530-R-10-012. Washington, DC:
       U.S EPA. .
       Accessed January 6, 2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2011. "Municipal Solid Waste Generation,
       Recycling, and Disposal in the United States: Facts and Figures for 2010." December
       2011. EPA-530-F-11-005. Washington, DC: U.S. EPA.
       .

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2012a. Landfill Gas Energy: A Guide to
       Developing and Implementing Greenhouse Gas Reduction Programs. State and Local
       Climate and Energy Program, U.S. EPA. 2012. EPA-430-R-09-047.
       .

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2012b. Office of Solid Waste and Emergency
       Response (OSWER), Office of Resource Conservation and Recovery (ORCR). Web
       page: Municipal Solid Waste Landfills.
       . Accessed December 4, 2012.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2012c. OSWER, ORCR. Web page: Closure and
       Post-Closure Care Requirements for Municipal Solid Waste Landfills.
                                         2-46

-------
       . Accessed
       December 4, 2012.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2012d. OSWER, ORCR. Web page: Municipal
       Solid Waste Landfills: Bioreactors.
       . Accessed
       December 4, 2012.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2012e. OSWER, ORCR. Web page: History of
       RCRA. . Accessed November 14,
       2012.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2012f. OSWER, ORCR. Web page: Transfer
       Stations, . Accessed
       November 14, 2012.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2012g. OSWER, ORCR. Web page: MSW
       Landfill Criteria Technical Manual.
       . Accessed December 4,
       2012.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2012h. Landfill Methane Outreach Program
       (LMOP), Climate Change Division, U.S. EPA. Web page: Frequent Questions: Landfill
       Gas. . Accessed December 3, 2012.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2013. An Overview of Landfill Gas Energy in the
       United States. LMOP, Climate Change Division, U.S. EPA. July 2013.
       .

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2014a. "Municipal Solid Waste Generation,
       Recycling, and Disposal in the United States: Facts and Figures  for 2012." February
       2014. EPA-530-F-14-001. Washington, DC: U.S. EPA.
       . Accessed January
       6,2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2014b. Landfill Gas Energy Cost Model
       (LFGcost-Web), Version 3.0. LMOP, Climate Change Division, U.S. EPA. August 2014.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2014c. "Landfill-level data only (all landfills) -
       updated August 2014." LMOP, Climate Change Division, U.S. EPA.
       .

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2014d. "Webinar: Using Landfill Gas as Vehicle
       Fuel." LMOP, Climate Change Division, U.S. EPA. November 13, 2014.
       .
                                        2-47

-------
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2015a. LFG Energy Project Development
      Handbook. LMOP, Climate Change Division, U.S. EPA. February 2015.
      .

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2015b. "Landfill and LFG Energy Project
      Database." LMOP, Climate Change Division, U.S. EPA. January 2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2015c. OSWER, ORCR. Web page: Non-
      Hazardous Waste Management Hierarchy."
      . Accessed January 22, 2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2015d. OSWER, ORCR. Web page: Municipal
      Solid Waste, . Accessed
      January 22, 2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2015e. OSWER, ORCR. Web page: Electricity
      from Municipal Solid Waste, . Accessed January 22, 2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2015f. LMOP. Web page: Frequent Questions:
      LFG Energy Projects. . Accessed January
      22,2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2015g. OSWER, ORCR. Web page: Types of
      Composting, . Accessed
      January 22, 2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2015. Inventory of U.S. Greenhouse Gas
      Emissions and Sinks: 1990-2013. Office of Atmospheric Programs, Washington, DC.
      EPA 430-R-15-004. Annex 3.14, Tables A-265 and Table ES-2. April 2015.
      . Accessed
      April 28, 2015.

 Waste 360. 2014. "Navigating the Complexities of Food Waste." September 25, 2014.
      .

Waste Business Journal (WBJ). 2010. "Landfill Tipping Fees Reach New Record, Despite Slow
      Times". August 17, 2010.
      .

WBJ. 2012a. "Waste Market Overview & Outlook 2012."
      . Accessed January 16, 2015.

WBJ. 2012b. "US Landfill Tipping Fees Reach $45 per Ton; Slow Volume Growth." October 2,
      2012. .
                                        2-48

-------
WBJ. 2014. "Directory of Waste Processing and Disposal Sites 2014."
       . Accessed January 6, 2015.

Wright, Shawn. 2012. Waste & Recycling News. "Tipping fees vary across the U.S." July 20,
       2012. Previously accessed at
       .
                                          2-49

-------
       3   REGULATORY PROGRAM COSTS AND EMISSIONS REDUCTIONS

3.1  Introduction

       Currently, the Emission Guidelines for existing MSW landfills requires landfills of at
least 2.5 million megagrams (Mg) capacity and 2.5 million cubic meters in size with estimated
nonmethane organic compounds (NMOC) emissions of at least 50 Mg per year to collect and
control or treat landfill gas (LFG). Landfills which meet the design size requirements but do not
emit at least 50 Mg NMOC per year are required to test and monitor. As part of this review, the
EPA evaluated the emission reductions and costs associated with a series of regulatory options.
This chapter of the RIA includes three sets of discussions related to the proposed new Emission
Guidelines:
   •   Emissions Analysis
   •   Engineering and Administrative Cost Analysis
   •   Regulatory Option Analysis
This discussion of the emissions and cost analyses is meant to assist the reader of the RIA to
better understand the regulatory impact analysis. However, we provide references to technical
memoranda for readers interested in a greater level of detail.

3.2  General Assumptions and Procedures

       The proposed Emission Guidelines will affect existing MSW landfills. Any changes to
the emission guidelines that might result from this review will ultimately apply to landfills that
accepted waste on or after November 8, 198712, and that commenced construction,
reconstruction, or modification prior to July 17, 2014 (the date of publication of proposed
revisions to the landfills NSPS, 40 CFR part 60, subpart XXX). However, the EPA recognizes
that many landfills subject to the proposed Subpart Cf are closed or contain inactive  areas that do
not produce as much landfill gas. Therefore, the EPA is proposing a separate subcategory for
12 This date in 1987 is the date on which permit programs were established under the Hazardous and Solid Waste
   Amendments of RCRA. This date was also selected as the regulatory cutoff in the EG for landfills no longer
   receiving wastes because EPA judged States would be able to identify active facilities as of this date.

                                           3-1

-------
landfills that closed after 1987 but on or before the date of this Emission Guidelines proposal.
These landfills would be subject to a 50 Mg/yr NMOC emission rate threshold, consistent with
the NMOC thresholds in Subparts Cc and WWW of Part 60. These landfills will also be exempt
from initial reporting requirements, provided that the landfill already met these requirements
under Subparts Cc or WWW of Part 60.
       To assess the impacts of the proposal, the EPA drew upon a comprehensive database of
existing landfills, derived from a landfill and LFG energy project database maintained by the
EPA's Landfill Methane Outreach Program (LMOP) and data from the Greenhouse Gas
Reporting Program (GHGRP). Unfortunately,  this dataset was missing some landfill data for
recent years (2010-2014) and included incomplete data for many landfills. To better represent
landfills from recent years, model landfills were created. These model future landfills were
developed by evaluating the most recently opened existing landfills and assuming that the sizes
and locations of landfills opening in 2010-2014 would be similar to the sizes and locations of
landfills that opened in the most recent complete 5 years of data (2005-2010). Based on this
assessment, the EPA created a total of five model landfills to represent landfills opening during
2010-2014, which combined with the five landfills for which construction was already  planned,
led to ten projected future landfills that would be subject to the Emission  Guidelines. In addition,
11 model landfills were created that would be  subject to the NSPS discussed in Chapter 7. The
creation of the landfill dataset is detailed in the docketed memorandum, "Summary of Landfill
Dataset Used in the Cost and Emission Reduction Analysis of Landfill Regulations. 2014."
       To estimate the cost and emission impacts of each regulatory  option, EPA determined
which landfills in the complete dataset met the design capacity  and emission rate thresholds for
each regulatory option, and then calculated the emission reductions and costs for each landfill
under each regulatory option in 2025 using the methods described below. The EPA is assessing
impacts in year 2025 as a representative year for the landfills Emission Guidelines. While the
year 2025 differs somewhat from the expected first year of implementation for the Emission
Guidelines (year 2020), the number of existing landfills required to install controls under the
proposed 2.5/34 option in year 2025 is comparable (within 2 percent  of those required to control
in the estimated first year of implementation. Further, year 2025 represents a year in which
several of the landfills subject to control requirements have had to expand their GCCS  according
the expansion lag times set forth in proposed subpart Cf. While the analysis focuses on impacts
                                          5-2

-------
in 2025, results for alternative years are also presented in Section 3.6. The resulting costs and
emission reductions incurred by each landfill were used to assess the overall impacts of the
current Emission Guidelines in the baseline and the incremental impacts of the regulatory
options considered. The emission reduction and cost and revenue equations and assumptions are
detailed in the docketed memorandum from ERG to EPA, "Updated Methodology for Estimating
Cost and Emission Impacts of Proposed MSW Landfill Regulations. 2015."

       The emissions and cost modeling was based upon the following basic assumptions:

    •   The baseline represents the emission reductions and costs associated with the
       requirements of Subpart Cc. Each regulatory option was compared to this baseline.
    •   Each landfill would install gas collection and control systems (GCCS)  when the landfill
       exceeds the emission rate and design capacity threshold.
    •   Each landfill would remove GCCS when the actual emissions are below the emissions
       threshold, the landfill is closed, and the controls have been in place for at least 15 years.
    •   Costs were annualized using a 7% interest rate, which is consistent with EPA guidance
       for cost evaluations. Costs are also presented using a 3% interest rate, in accordance with
       OMB guidance.
Alternative regulatory options varied the emission rate thresholds and design capacity thresholds.

3.3   Emissions Analysis

       To estimate emission reductions, the amount of LFG and NMOC emitted at each landfill
was estimated using a model programmed in Microsoft® Access.  The model  assumes that the
collection equipment is installed and operational at the landfill 30 months after the emissions
exceed the NMOC emission threshold in each option13. As the landfill is filled over time, the
13 Note that even though the proposed rule allows a 30-month initial lag time, the model actually assumes the
   collection equipment is installed and operational at 36 months. We modeled as a 36 month (3-year) lag time
   since the first-order decay equation used to model emissions is on an annual, instead of monthly, basis. Further,
   because the current rule requires annual NMOC emission reports to be submitted by 6 months into the following
   calendar year, the landfill would have 30 months after the submittal of its first NMOC emission report showing
   an exceedance to install the GCCS, which is approximately 36 months after the excess emissions occurred.

                                            3-3

-------
model assumes the landfill expands the GCCS into new areas of waste placement in accordance
with the expansion lag time of the standard.  Once the landfill has reached maximum gas
production, gas generation will begin to decline once waste is no longer accepted. At this point,
the analysis assumes that the GCCS no longer needs to be expanded and the GCCS will continue
to collect all the gas being produced until the gas production falls back below the emission
threshold of the proposed standard and the GCCS has been installed for at least 15 years. The
emission reductions are equal to the amount of collected NMOC or methane that is combusted,
which is estimated by multiplying the amount of collected gas by a destruction efficiency of 98
percent.14

       In addition to direct emission reductions, the proposed Emission Guidelines are expected
to have secondary air impacts due to the additional energy demand required to operate the
control system and the by-product emissions from the combustion of LFG. However, these are
offset by avoided emissions from the national electrical grid as landfills generate electricity from
the LFG. The methodology used to estimate secondary impacts of the proposed Emission
Guidelines are detailed in the docketed memorandum from ERG to EPA, "Estimating Secondary
Impacts of the Landfills Emission Guidelines Review. 2015"

3.4  Engineering and Administrative Cost Analysis

       The evaluation will assume that landfills will install and remove LFG controls as required
by the rule. Landfills are required to install controls when the landfill exceeds the emission rate
and design capacity thresholds. Landfills are allowed to remove controls when the actual
emissions  are below the emissions threshold, the landfill is closed, and the controls have been in
place for at least  15 years.

       The EPA derived the cost equations used in the evaluation from the EPA's Landfill Gas
Energy Cost Model (LFGcost-Web), version 3.0, which was developed by the EPA's Landfill
14 The regulatory analysis models collectable gas (see ERG. 2015. Updated Methodology for Estimating Cost and
   Emission Impacts of MSW Landfills Regulations). As per 60.34(f)(b)(2)(i), the GCCS should be designed to
   handle the maximum expected gas flow rate from the entire area of the landfill that warrants control over the
   intended use period of the gas control system equipment.

                                          3-4

-------
Methane Outreach Program (LMOP). LFGcost-Web estimates gas collection, flare, and energy
recovery system costs and was developed based on cost data obtained from equipment vendors
and consulting firms that have installed and operated numerous gas collection and control
systems. LFGcost-Web encompasses the types of costs included in the EPA OAQPS control
cost manual including capital costs, annual costs, and revenue from LFG electricity sales.  Total
capital costs include purchased equipment costs, installation costs, engineering and design costs,
costs for site preparation and buildings, costs of permits and fees, and working capital.  Total
annual compliance costs include direct costs, indirect costs, and revenue from LFG electricity
sales. Direct annual costs are those that are proportional to a facility-specific metric such  as the
facility's productive output or size.  Indirect annual costs are independent of facility-specific
metrics and may include categories such as administrative charges, taxes, or insurance.

       For this evaluation, the EPA assessed costs in 2012$. The costs included in LFGcost-
Web are in 2013$ and were adjusted for inflation to 2012$ using a factor of 2 percent for capital
costs and 2.5 percent for O&M costs.15 For the primary estimate of costs, the EPA used an
interest rate of 7% to annualize the capital costs in this evaluation to estimate the annual capital
cost of flares, wells, wellheads (including piping to collect gas), and engines  over the  lifetime of
the equipment. Costs were also estimated using an interest rate of 3%. The EPA assumes that the
equipment will be replaced when its lifetime is over, so the annualized capital costs are incurred
as long  as the landfill still has controls in place. In order to calculate the annualization factors,
the EPA assumes that flares, wells, well heads, and engines have a 15-year lifetime. In addition,
there is  a mobilization/installation charge to bring well  drilling equipment on site each time the
gas collection system is expanded.  Because the landfill  will be drilling wells  to expand the
control  system during the expansion lag year, EPA assumes that this capital installation cost has
a lifetime equal to the expansion lag time.
15 The inflation rate for capital equipment is consistent with the default equipment inflation rate in the LFGcost-Web
   model; the inflation rate for O&M costs is consistent with the default general inflation rate in the LFGcost-Web
   model. See further documentation at: http://epa.gov/lmop/publications-tools/lfgcost/LFGcost-
   WebV3_Omanual.pdf

                                            3-5

-------
       A number of the capital costs equations are dependent upon the number of wells at each
landfill. In order to estimate the number of wells at each landfill, EPA estimated the number of
acres that have been filled with waste for each landfill for each year.  We assumed that the
percentage of design area filled (acres) would track the ratio of waste in place/design capacity
(e.g., is a landfill has a waste-in-place amount equivalent to 40% of design capacity, then 40% of
the planned acreage is filled).  EPA assumed that each landfill would install one well per acre
and that the number of wells would increase periodically based on  expansion lag time.

       Engines are assumed to be installed only at landfills that produce enough LFG to power
the engine and only when the electricity buyback rates allow the operation of the engine to be
profitable.  Standard engines used at landfills  have approximately 1 MW capacity, which equates
to 195  million ft3 per year of collected LFG (at 50 percent methane).  Therefore, engines are
assumed to be installed at landfills that have at least 195 million ft3 per year of collected LFG for
at least 15 years.

       EPA calculated  and summed the engine capital and operation and maintenance (O&M)
equations to determine at what electricity buyback rate an engine is profitable.  The profitable
electricity buyback rates are rates that are greater than $0.0457 per kWh at 7% and greater than
$0.0430 per kWh at 3% interest. Engines were only assumed to be installed in states with
buyback rates exceeding those values.

       Multiple engines may be present at a landfill when there is  sufficient gas flow to support
additional  engines. As noted above, one engine requires 195 million ft3 per year of collected
LFG, so in order to have two engines on-site,  the landfill must have double that amount of LFG
(390 million ft3 per year) for at least 15 years.

       The capital costs for engines are based on the capital costs for standard reciprocating
engine-generator sets in LFGcost-Web.  These costs include gas compression and treatment to
remove particulates and moisture (e.g., a chiller), reciprocating engine and generator, electrical
interconnect equipment, and site work including housings, utilities, and total facility engineering,
design, and permitting.

-------
       Several of the compliance requirements require labor to complete the activities in
addition to capital expenses for purchasing the monitoring and control equipment. This analysis
assumes that a Civil Engineer or Civil Engineer Technician completes compliance requirements
of the proposed amendments, depending on the complexity of the task. Some landfill owners or
operators do all or a portion of this work directly while others contract out control installation or
monitoring requirements.

3.5  Regulatory Baseline and Options

       As mentioned before, the alternative regulatory options differ from the baseline by
varying in the design capacity thresholds and emission rate thresholds:

   •   Baseline: design capacity retained at 2.5 Mg, emission threshold retained at 50 Mg
       NMOC/year
   •   Alternative Option 2.5/40: design capacity retained at 2.5 Mg, emission threshold
       reduced to 40 NMOC Mg/yr
   •   Proposed Option 2.5/34: design capacity retained at 2.5 Mg, emission threshold reduced
       to 34 NMOC Mg/yr
   •   Alternative Option 2.0/34: design capacity reduced to 2.0 Mg, emission threshold
       reduced to 34 Mg NMOC/year

       The baseline reflects the parameters of the current Emission Guidelines.  In the baseline,
the Emission Guidelines affect 989 landfills, with 574 landfills controlling emissions, 211
landfills reporting but not controlling emissions, and 233 landfills in the closed subcategory in
2025.
                                           5-7

-------
Table 3-1  Number of Affected Landfills in 2025 under the Baseline and Alternative
Options
                                                                                       Open
                                                                                     Landfills
                    Affected                                Closed       Open      Reporting
                    Landfills     Affected     Affected     Landfills     Landfills     but Not
                    (Open and      Open       Closed    Controlling  Controlling  Controlling
	Closed)	Landfills    Subcategory   Emissions    Emissions    Emissions
 Current EG = 2.5 million Mg and m3 design capacity and 50 Mg/yr NMOC
 Baseline
989
756
233
29
545
211
 Alternative EG Options
Alternative
option 2. 5/40
Proposed option
2.5/34
Alternative
option 2.0/34
989
989

1090
756
756

803
233
233

287
29
29

29
607
651

667
149
105

136
 Note: Affected landfills include landfills subject to rule based on size and open as of 2015 as well as landfills in the closed
 subcategory. Affected open landfills are comprised of open landfills controlling emissions and open landfills reporting but
 not controlling emissions. Some closed landfills are still controlling emissions in 2025.
       Based on the characteristics of the landfills, the proposed option presented in Table 3-1
would require 106 additional landfills to install controls by 2025. The less stringent alternative
option would require 62 additional landfills to install controls by 2025, while the more stringent
alternative option would affect 101 additional landfills, with some being required only to report,
others being required to control, and some being in the closed subcategory. In that option, 122
additional landfills are required to install controls by 2025.

 Under the proposed option 2.5/34, the emission reductions would be an additional 2,770 Mg
NMOC and 436,100 Mg methane (10,900,000 Mg CO2 Eq.) compared to the baseline in 2025.
The less stringent alternative option 2.5/40 would yield emissions reductions of 1,720 Mg
NMOC and 270,700 Mg methane (6,800,000 Mg CO2 Eq.) compared to the baseline, while the
more stringent alternative option 2.0/34 would result in emissions reductions of 3,040 Mg
NMOC and 479,100 Mg methane (12,000,000 Mg CO2Eq.) compared to the baseline.  The wide
range in magnitude  of emission reductions among pollutants is due to the composition of landfill

-------
gas: NMOC represents less than 1 percent of landfill gas, while methane represents
approximately 50 percent. The emission reductions are summarized in Table 3-2.

Table 3-2  Estimated Annual Average Emissions Reductions in 2025 for the Baseline and
Alternative Options
                                       	Annual Average Reduction (Mg)	
                                                                              Methane
                                                                              (in CO2-
                                               NMOC	Methane    equivalents)*
 Current EG = 2.5 million Mg and m3 design capacity and 50 Mg/yr NMOC
Baseline
Incremental values versus the current EG
Alternative option 2.5/40
Proposed option 2.5/34
Alternative option 2.0/34
57,300
1,720
2,770
3,040
9,035,000
270,700
436,100
479,100
226,000,000
6,800,000
10,900,000
12,000,000
 *A global warming potential of 25 is used to convert methane to CCh-equivalents. Secondary CCh emission
 reductions are not included in this table.
       Under the proposed option 2.5/34, when using a 7% discount rate the additional cost of
control over the baseline in 2025 is estimated to be $101 million, $55.3 million of which is
estimated to be offset by increased revenue from beneficial-use projects, so the net cost is
estimated to be $46.8 million (Table 3-3). The additional cost of control for the less stringent
alternative option 2.5/40 is estimated to be $60.3 million, $33.6 million of which is estimated to
be offset by increased revenue from beneficial-use projects, so the net cost is estimated to be $27
million. The cost of control for the more stringent alternative option 2.0/34 is estimated to be
$111 million, $60.7 million of which is estimated to be offset by increased revenue from
beneficial-use projects, so the net cost is estimated to be $51 million. These options represent
approximately between 9 to 17 percent in additional net costs beyond the baseline, with the
proposed option 2.5/34 resulting in a 16 percent increase in net costs beyond the baseline for the
industry as a whole.
                                           5-9

-------
Table 3-3  Estimated Engineering Compliance Costs in 2025 for Baseline and Alternative
Options (7% Discount Rate)
Estimated Annualized Net Cost (Millions 2012$)
Testing and
Monitoring
Costs
Revenue from
Beneficial-use
Control Costs Projects Net Cost
 Current EG = 2.5 million Mg and m3 design capacity and 50 Mg/yr NMOC
Baseline 7.3
Incremental values versus the current EG
Alternative option 2.5/40 0.40
Proposed option 2.5/34 0.69
Alternative option 2.0/34 0.84
1,700

60.3
101
111
1,410

33.6
55.3
60.7
299

27.0
46.8
51.0
Note: All total are independently rounded and may not sum.
       When using a 3% discount rate, the model predicts a different timing in the investment
behavior by the landfills, which affects both the costs and revenue that are predicted in 2025.
Under the proposed option 2.5/34, the additional cost of control over the baseline in 2025 is
estimated to be $117 million, $82.5 million of which is estimated to be offset in increased
revenue from beneficial-use projects, so the net cost is estimated to be $35 million (Table 3-4).
The cost of control for the less stringent alternative option 2.5/40 is estimated to be $72.1
million, $52.3 million of which is estimated to be offset by increased revenue from beneficial use
projects, so the net cost is estimated to be $20.1 million. The cost of control for the more
stringent alternative option 2.0/34 is estimated to be $126 million, of which $89.1 million is
estimated to be offset by increased revenue from beneficial-use projects, so the net cost is
estimated to be $38.1 million. These options represent approximately between 24 to 45 percent
in additional net costs beyond the baseline, with the proposed option 2.5/34 resulting in a 41
percent increase in net costs beyond the baseline for the industry as a whole. However, it is
important to note that the baseline value when using a 3%  discount rate is less than 30 percent of
the value when using a 7% discount rate, because the increased costs of earlier installation of
GCCS and engines are offset by increased revenue from energy generation.
                                          3-10

-------
Table 3-4  Estimated Engineering Compliance Costs in 2025 for Baseline and Alternative
Options (3% Discount Rate)
Estimated Annualized Net Cost (Millions 2012$)
Testing and
Monitoring
Costs
Revenue from
Beneficial-use
Control Costs Projects Net Cost
 Current EG = 2.5 million Mg and m3 design capacity and 50 Mg/yr NMOC
Baseline 7.1
Incremental values versus the current EG
Alternative option 2.5/40 0.37
Proposed option 2.5/34 0.66
Alternative option 2.0/34 0.80
2,190

72.1
117
126
2,120

52.3
82.5
89.1
84.5

20.1
35.0
38.1
Note: All total are independently rounded and may not sum.
       In terms of cost effectiveness, when considering the estimated net cost of the options, the
overall average cost effectiveness for NMOC reductions is $5,200 per Mg NMOC under the
baseline and roughly $17,000 per Mg NMOC under the proposed option 2.5/34 and alternative
option 2.0/34, and roughly $16,000 per Mg NMOC under the alternative option 2.5/40 (Table
3-5). The average cost-effectiveness  of controlling methane is significantly lower than for
NMOC because methane constitutes approximately 50 percent of landfill gas, while NMOC
represents less than 1 percent of landfill gas. The overall average cost effectiveness for methane
reductions is roughly $33 per Mg methane under the baseline and approximately $100 - $110 per
Mg methane under the proposed option 2.5/34 and the alternative options 2.5/40 and 2.0/34.

       When estimating cost effectiveness excluding the estimated revenue from beneficial-use
projects, the overall average cost effectiveness for NMOC reductions is $29,800 per Mg NMOC
under the baseline and roughly $37,000 per Mg NMOC under the proposed option 2.5/34 and
alternative option 2.0/34, and roughly $36,000 per Mg NMOC under the alternative option
2.5/40 (Table 3-5). The average cost-effectiveness of controlling methane is significantly lower
than for NMOC because methane constitutes approximately 50 percent of landfill gas, while
NMOC represents less than 1 percent of landfill gas. The overall average cost effectiveness for
methane reductions is $189 per Mg methane under the baseline and approximately $225 - $235
per Mg methane under the proposed  option 2.5/34 and the alternative options 2.5/40 and 2.0/34.
                                          3-11

-------
Table 3-5  Estimated Cost-effectiveness in 2025 for the Baseline and Alternative Options
(7% Discount Rate)

                             	Cost-effectiveness (2012$ per Mg)	
                                                                              Methane
                                    NMOC              Methane             (in CO2-
                             	equivalents)*
                                Net      Total      Net       Total       Net      Total
                                Costb      Cost      Costb     Cost      Costb      Cost
	/ton	/ton	/ton	/ton	/ton	/ton

         Current EG = 2.5 million Mg and m3 design capacity and 50 Mg/yr NMOC
Baseline 5,200 29,800
Incremental values versus
Alternative option 2.5/40 15,800 35,500
Proposed option 2. 5/34 17,000 37,000
Alternative option 2.0/34 16,800 36,900
33.1 189
the current EG
100 225
108 235
107 234
1.3

4.0
4.3
4.3
7.6

9.0
9.4
9.4
Note: The cost-effectiveness of NMOC and methane are estimated as if all of the control cost were attributed to each
pollutant separately.
a A global warming potential of 25 is used to convert methane to CO2-equivalents. The secondary CC>2 emission
reductions are not reflected in these estimates.
b Net Cost is the total control and testing and monitoring cost minus any project revenue. The control costs for
landfills with energy projects includes costs to install and operate a reciprocating engine (and associated electrical
equipment), which is more expensive than a standard flare. Reciprocating engines are not required by the regulation
but are expected to be used as control devices when it is cost-effective to recovery the LFG energy.
3.6    Alternative Years of Analysis

       While the EPA is assessing impacts in year 2025 as a representative year for the landfills

Emission Guidelines for existing MSW landfills, the quantity and composition of landfill gas

does change over the lifetime of a landfill, as discussed in Chapter 2. This section presents a

more complete picture of the emission reductions and costs of the Emission Guidelines

alternatives over time by presenting results from the years 2020, 2030, and 2040. Throughout

this section, costs are presented only at a 7% interest rate, and do not include testing and

monitoring costs. However, testing and monitoring costs are typically a very small percentage of

the overall costs. Tables 3-6 and 3-7 present the emissions reductions and compliance costs,

respectively, of the alternatives in the 2020 snapshot year.
                                             3-12

-------
Table 3-6  Estimated Annual Average Emissions Reductions in 2020 for the Baseline and
Alternative Options

                                      	Annual Average Reduction (Mg)	
                                                                            Million
                                                                           Methane
                                                              Million      (in CO2-
                                             NMOC	Methane    equivalents)*
 Current EG = 2.5 million Mg and m3 design capacity and 50 Mg/yr NMOC	
 Baseline                                    56,300             8.9          222

 Incremental values versus the current EG
Alternative option 2.5/40
Proposed option 2.5/34
Alternative option 2.0/34
1,490
2,270
2,560
0.24
0.36
0.40
5.9
9.0
10.1
 *A global warming potential of 25 is used to convert methane to CCh-equivalents. Secondary CCh emission
 reductions are not included in this table.
Table 3-7  Estimated Engineering Compliance Costs in 2020 for Baseline and Alternative
Options (7% Discount Rate)
                                             Estimated Annualized Net Cost (Millions
                                                             2012$)
Landfills
Controlling
Emissions
Control Costs
Revenue from
Beneficial-use
Projects
Net Cost
 Current EG = 2.5 million Mg and m3 design capacity and 50 Mg/yr NMOC	
 Baseline                        595           1,660           1,390           262

                       Incremental values versus the current EG
Alternative option 2.5/40
Proposed option 2.5/34
Alternative option 2.0/34
57
93
108
53.0
88.4
96.9
42.9
65.8
70.0
18.1
30.5
34.9
Note: All total are independently rounded and may not sum.

Tables 3-8 and 3-9 present the emissions reductions and compliance costs, respectively, in the
2030 snapshot year.
                                         3-13

-------
Table 3-8  Estimated Annual Average Emissions Reductions in 2030 for the Baseline and
Alternative Options

                                     	Annual Average Reduction (Mg)	
                                                                           Million
                                                                           Methane
                                                             Million       (in CO2-
                                            NMOC	Methane     equivalents)*
 Current EG = 2.5 million Mg and m3 design capacity and 50 Mg/yr NMOC	
 Baseline                                   55,600            8.8           219

 Incremental values versus the current EG
Alternative option 2.5/40
Proposed option 2.5/34
Alternative option 2.0/34
1,960
3,150
3,390
0.31
0.50
0.53
7.7
12.4
13.4
 *A global warming potential of 25 is used to convert methane to CCh-equivalents. Secondary CCh emission
 reductions are not included in this table.
Table 3-9  Estimated Engineering Compliance Costs in 2030 for Baseline and Alternative
Options (7% Discount Rate)
                                             Estimated Annualized Net Cost (Millions
                                                             2012$)
Landfills
Controlling
Emissions
Control Costs
Revenue from
Beneficial-use
Projects
Net Cost
 Current EG = 2.5 million Mg and m3 design capacity and 50 Mg/yr NMOC	
 Baseline                        554           1,680           1,360          325

                       Incremental values versus the current EG
Alternative option 2.5/40
Proposed option 2.5/34
Alternative option 2.0/34
65
107
123
69.4
112.9
122.4
31.5
58.5
63.9
32.9
49.4
53.5
Note: All total are independently rounded and may not sum.
                                         3-14

-------
Tables 3-10 and 3-11 present the emissions reductions and compliance costs, respectively, in the
2040 snapshot year.

Table 3-10  Estimated Annual Average Emissions Reductions in 2040 for the Baseline and
Alternative Options

                                      	Annual Average Reduction (Mg)	
                                                                             Million
                                                                            Methane
                                                               Million       (in CO2-
                                             NMOC	Methane    equivalents)*
 Current EG = 2.5 million Mg and m3 design capacity and 50 Mg/yr NMOC	
 Baseline                                    49,500             7.8            195

 Incremental values versus the current EG	
 Alternative option 2.5/40                      1,340              0.21           5.3
 Proposed option 2.5/34                        2,130              0.34           8.4
 Alternative option 2.0/34	2,210	O35	8^
 *A global warming potential of 25 is used to convert methane to CCh-equivalents. Secondary CCh emission
 reductions are not included in this table.
Table 3-11  Estimated Engineering Compliance Costs in 2040 for Baseline and Alternative
Options (7% Discount Rate)
Estimated Annualized Net Cost
2012$)

Current EG = 2.5
Baseline
Alternative option
Proposed option 2.
Alternative option
Landfills
Controlling
Emissions
million Mg and m3 design
Control Costs
capacity and
Revenue from
Beneficial-use
Projects
50 Mg/yr NMOC
464 1,500 1,100
Incremental values versus the current EG
2.5/40 47
5/34 74
2.0/34 81
51.6
89.4
93.0
26.7
56.4
58.2
(Millions
Net Cost

398
27.0
35.0
36.7
Note: All total are independently rounded and may not sum.
                                          3-15

-------
                    4   BENEFITS OF EMISSIONS REDUCTIONS

4.1  Introduction

       The proposed Emission Guidelines are expected to result in significant emissions
reductions of landfill gas (LFG) from existing MSW landfills. By lowering the NMOC emissions
threshold to 34 Mg/yr, the proposal is anticipated to achieve reductions of 2,770 Mg/yr NMOC
and 436,100 Mg/yr methane in 2025. The NMOC portion of LFG can contain a variety of air
pollutants, including VOC and various organic HAP. VOC emissions are precursors to both fine
particulate matter (PM2.s) and ozone formation, while methane is a GHG and a precursor to
global ozone formation.  As described in the subsequent sections, these pollutants are associated
with substantial health effects, climate effects, and other welfare effects.  The only categories of
benefits monetized in this RIA are methane-related climate effects and CO2 co-benefits
associated with reduced  electricity demand due to increased generation of electricity by landfills
through the burning of LFG in engines. The methane-related climate benefits are estimated to
range from $310 million (2012$) to $1.7 billion (2012$); these benefits are estimated to be $660
million (2012$) in 2025  using a 3% discount rate.  The CO2 co-benefits are estimated to range
from $3.6 million (2012$) to $36 million (2012$) in 2025; estimated CO2 benefits are $12
million (2012$) in 2025  using a 3% discount rate.

       While we expect that these avoided emissions  will also result in improvements in air
quality and reduce health and welfare effects associated with exposure to HAP, ozone, and fine
particulate matter (PM2.s), we have determined that quantification of those health benefits cannot
be accomplished for this rule in a defensible way.  This is not to imply that these benefits do not
exist; rather, it is a reflection of the difficulties in modeling the direct and indirect impacts of the
reductions in emissions for this industrial sector with the data currently available. With the data
available, we are not able to provide a credible health  PM2.5 benefits estimates for this rule, due
to the differences in the locations of MSW landfill emission points  relative to existing
information and the highly localized nature of air quality responses associated with HAP and
                                           4-1

-------
VOC reductions.16 Nearly 30 organic HAPs have been identified in uncontrolled LFG, including

benzene, ethylbenzene, toluene, and vinyl chloride, and they will be reduced by this rule. In this

chapter, we provide a qualitative assessment of the health benefits associated with reducing

exposure to these pollutants, as well as visibility impairment and ecosystem benefits. Table 4-1

summarizes the quantified and unquantified benefits in this analysis.
Table 4-1 Climate and Human Health Effects of Emission Reductions in this Rule
Category
Effect Has
Specific Effect Been
Quantified
Effect Has , ,
_ More
Been T _
,, .. , Information
Monetized
Improved Environment
Reduced climate
effects
Global climate impacts from methane (CH4) l
and carbon dioxide (CCh)
Other climate impacts (e.g., ozone, black
carbon, aerosols, other impacts)
Marten et al.
S (2014), SC-C02
TSDs
IPCC, Ozone ISA,
PM ISA2
Improved Human Health
Reduced incidence of
premature mortality
from exposure to
PM2.5
morbidity from
exposure to PM2.5
Adult premature mortality based on cohort
study estimates and expert elicitation estimates —
(age >25 or age >30)
Infant mortality (age < 1 ) —
Non- fatal heart attacks (age > 1 8) —
Hospital admissions — respiratory (all ages) —
Hospital admissions — cardiovascular (age >20) —
Emergency room visits for asthma (all ages) —
Acute bronchitis (age 8-12) —
Lower respiratory symptoms (age 7-14) —
Upper respiratory symptoms (asthmatics age 9-
11) ~~
Asthma exacerbation (asthmatics age 6-18) —
Lost work days (age 1 8-65) —
Minor restricted-activity days (age 1 8-65) —
Chronic Bronchitis (age >26) —
Emergency room visits for cardiovascular
effects (all ages)
— PM ISA3
— PM ISA3
— PM ISA3
— PM ISA3
— PM ISA3
— PM ISA3
— PM ISA3
— PM ISA3
— PMISA3
— PMISA3
— PMISA3
— PMISA3
— PMISA3
— PMISA3
16 Previous studies have estimated the monetized benefits-per-ton of reducing VOC emissions associated with the
   effect that those emissions have on ambient PM2 5 levels and the health effects associated with PM2 5 exposure
   (Fann, Fulcher, and Hubbell, 2009).  While these ranges of benefit-per-ton estimates provide useful context, the
   geographic distribution of VOC emissions from the MSW landfill sector are not consistent with emissions
   modeled in Fann, Fulcher, and Hubbell (2009). In addition, the benefit-per-ton estimates for VOC emission
   reductions in that study are derived from total VOC emissions across all sectors. Coupled with the larger
   uncertainties about the relationship between VOC emissions and PM2 5 and the highly localized nature of air
   quality responses associated with VOC reductions, these factors lead us to conclude that the available VOC
   benefit-per-ton estimates are not appropriate to calculate monetized benefits of these rules, even as a bounding
   exercise.
                                                4-2

-------
      Category
              Specific Effect
Effect Has
   Been
Quantified
Effect Has
   Been
Monetized
   More
Information
                       Strokes and cerebrovascular disease (age 50-
                       79)	
                       Other cardiovascular effects (e.g., other ages)
                       Other respiratory effects (e.g., pulmonary
                       function, non-asthma ER visits, non-bronchitis
                       chronic diseases, other ages and populations)
                       Reproductive and developmental effects (e.g.,
                       low birth weight, pre-term births, etc)	
                       Cancer, mutagenicity, and genotoxicity effects
                                                                          PMISA3
                                                                          PM ISA2
                                                                          PMISA2
                                                                          PMISA2'4
                                                                          PMISA2'4
 Reduced incidence of
 mortality from
 exposure to ozone
Premature mortality based on short-term study
estimates (all ages)	
Premature mortality based on long-term study
estimates (age 30-99)	
                             Ozone ISA3
                             Ozone ISA3
                       Hospital admissions—respiratory causes (age >
                       65)	
                       Hospital admissions—respiratory causes (age
                       Emergency department visits for asthma (all
                       ages)	
 Reduced incidence of
 morbidity from
 exposure to ozone
Minor restricted-activity days (age 18-65)
School absence days (age 5-17)
                       Decreased outdoor worker productivity (age
                       18-65)	
                       Other respiratory effects (e.g., premature aging
                       of lungs)	
                       Cardiovascular and nervous system effects
                       Reproductive and developmental effects
                                                                          Ozone ISA3
                                                                                                 Ozone ISA3
                                                                          Ozone ISA3
                             Ozone ISA3
                             Ozone ISA3
                                                                          Ozone ISA3
                                                                          Ozone ISA2
                                                                          Ozone ISA2
                                                                          Ozone ISA2-4
 Reduced incidence of
 morbidity from
 exposure to HAP
Effects associated with exposure to hazardous
air pollutants such as benzene
                             ATSDR, IRIS2'3
 Improved Environment
 Reduced visibility
 impairment
Visibility in Class 1 areas
Visibility in residential areas
                                                                                                 PMISA3
                             PMISA3
 Reduced effects from
 PM deposition
 (organics)	
Effects on Individual organisms and
ecosystems
                             PM ISA2
                       Visible foliar injury on vegetation
                       Reduced vegetation growth and reproduction
                       Yield and quality of commercial forest
                       products and crops	
 Reduced vegetation
 and ecosystem effects
 from exposure to
                       Damage to urban ornamental plants
Carbon sequestration in terrestrial ecosystems
Recreational demand associated with forest
aesthetics
                       Other non-use effects
                       Ecosystem functions (e.g., water cycling,
                       biogeochemical cycles, net primary
                       productivity, leaf-gas exchange, community
                       composition)	
                                                                          Ozone ISA3
                                                                          Ozone ISA3
                                                                          Ozone ISA3
                                                                          Ozone ISA2
                             Ozone ISA3
                                                                                                 Ozone ISA2
                                                                          Ozone ISA2
                                                                          Ozone ISA2
1 The global climate and related impacts of CO2 and CH4 emissions changes, such as sea level rise, are estimated within each
   integrated assessment model as part of the calculation of the SC-CO2 and SC-CH/i. The resulting monetized damages, which
   are relevant for conducting the benefit-cost analysis, are used in this RIA to estimate the welfare effects of quantified changes
   in CO2 emissions.
                                                       4-3

-------
2 We assess these benefits qualitatively because we do not have sufficient confidence in available data or methods.
3 We assess these benefits qualitatively due to data limitations for this analysis, but we have quantified them in other analyses.
4 We assess these benefits qualitatively because current evidence is only suggestive of causality or there are other significant
   concerns over the strength of the association.

4.2   Methane (CH4)

4.2.1   Methane climate effects and valuation

       Methane is the one of the principal components of landfill gas.  Methane is also a potent
greenhouse gas (GHG) that once emitted into the atmosphere absorbs terrestrial infrared
radiation that contributes to increased global warming and continuing climate change. Methane
reacts in the atmosphere to form ozone and ozone also impacts global temperatures. Methane, in
addition to other GHG emissions, contributes to warming of the atmosphere, which over time
leads to increased air and ocean temperatures, changes in precipitation patterns, melting and
thawing of global glaciers and ice, increasingly severe weather events, such as hurricanes of
greater intensity, and sea level rise, among other impacts.

       According to the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) Fifth Assessment
Report (AR5, 2015), changes in methane concentrations since 1750 contributed 0.48 W/m2 of
forcing, which is about 17% of all global forcing due to increases in anthropogenic GHG
concentrations, and which makes methane the second leading long-lived climate forcer after
CO2. However, after accounting for changes in other greenhouse substances such as ozone and
stratospheric water vapor due to chemical reactions of methane in the atmosphere, historical
methane emissions were estimated to have contributed to 0.97 W/m2 of forcing today, which is
about 30% of the contemporaneous forcing due to historical greenhouse gas emissions.

       MSW landfills emit significant amounts of methane. The Inventory of U.S. Greenhouse
Gas Emissions and Sinks: 1990-2013 (published April 2015) estimates 2013 methane emissions
from MSW landfills to be 97.5 MMt CO2 Eq. In 2013, total  methane emissions from MSW
landfills represented approximately 15 percent of the total methane emissions from all sources
and account for about 1.5 percent of all CCh-equivalent (CChEq.) emissions in the U.S., with
landfills being the third largest contributor to U.S. anthropogenic methane emissions (EPA,
2015).

                                           4-4

-------
       This rulemaking proposes emission control technologies and regulatory alternatives that
are expected to significantly decrease methane emissions from existing MSW landfills. By
lowering the NMOC emissions threshold to 34 Mg/yr, the proposal would achieve reductions of
2,770 Mg/yr NMOC and 436,100 Mg/yr methane in 2025.

       We calculated the global  social benefits of methane emissions reductions expected from
the proposed guidelines for existing MSW landfills using estimates of the social cost of methane
(SC-CH/t), a metric that estimates the monetary value of impacts associated with marginal
changes in methane emissions in a given year. It includes a wide range of anticipated climate
impacts, such as net changes in agricultural productivity and human health, property damage
from increased flood risk, and changes in energy system costs, such as reduced costs for heating
and increased costs for air conditioning. The SC-CH4 estimates applied in this analysis were
developed by Marten et al. (2014) and are discussed in greater detail below.

       A similar metric, the social cost of CO2 (SC-CCh), provides important context for
understanding the Marten et al. SC-CH4 estimates.  Estimates of the SC-CCh have been used by
EPA and other federal agencies to value the impacts of CO2 emissions changes in benefit cost
analysis for GHG-related rulemakings since 2008. The SC-CO2 is a metric that estimates the
monetary value of impacts associated with marginal changes in CO2 emissions in a given year.
Similar to the SC-CH4, it includes a wide range of anticipated climate impacts, such as net
changes in agricultural productivity, property damage from increased flood risk,  and changes in
energy system costs, such as reduced costs for heating and increased costs for air conditioning.  It
is used to quantify the benefits of reducing CO2 emissions, or the disbenefit from increasing
emissions, in regulatory impact analyses.

       The SC-CO2 estimates were  developed over many years, using the best science available,
and with input from the public. Specifically, an interagency working group (IWG) that included
EPA and other executive branch  agencies and offices used three integrated assessment models
(lAMs) to develop the SC-CCh estimates and recommended four global values for use in
regulatory analyses. The SC-CCh estimates were first released in February 2010 and updated in
2013 using new versions of each IAM.  The 2013 update did not revisit the 2010 modeling
decisions with regards to the discount rate, reference case socioeconomic and emission scenarios,
                                          4-5

-------
and equilibrium climate sensitivity distribution. Rather, improvements in the way damages are
modeled are confined to those that have been incorporated into the latest versions of the models
by the developers themselves and published in the peer-reviewed literature. The 2010 SC-CCh
Technical Support Document (2010 SC-CO2 TSD) provides a complete discussion of the
methods used to develop these estimates and the current SC-CCh TSD presents and discusses the
2013 update (including recent minor technical corrections to the estimates).17

       The 2010 SC-CO2 TSD noted a number of limitations to the SC-CO2 analysis, including
the incomplete way in which the lAMs capture catastrophic and non-catastrophic impacts, their
incomplete treatment of adaptation and technological change, uncertainty in the extrapolation of
damages to high temperatures, and assumptions regarding risk aversion. Currently lAMs do not
assign value to all of the important physical, ecological, and economic impacts of climate change
recognized in the climate change literature due to a lack of precise information on the nature of
damages and because the science incorporated into these models understandably lags behind the
most recent research. Nonetheless, these estimates and the discussion of their limitations
represent the best available information about the social benefits of CO2 reductions to inform
benefit-cost analysis; see RIA of this rule and the SC-CO2 TSDs for additional details. The new
versions of the models offer some improvements in these areas, although further work is
warranted.

       Accordingly, EPA and other agencies continue to engage in research on modeling and
valuation of climate impacts with the goal to improve these estimates.  The EPA and other
agencies also continue to consider feedback on the SC-CO2 estimates from stakeholders through
a range of channels, including public comments on Agency rulemakings that use the SC-CO2 in
supporting analyses and through regular interactions with stakeholders and research analysts
implementing the SC-CO2 methodology used by the interagency working group. In addition,
OMB's Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs sought public comment on the approach
17 Both the 2010 SC-CO2 TSD and the current TSD are available at: htrps://www. whitehouse.gov/omb/oira/social-
   cost-of-carbon.
                                          4-6

-------
used to develop the SC-CCh estimates through a separate comment period that ended on
February 26, 2014.

       After careful evaluation of the full range of comments, the interagency working group
continues to recommend the use of the SC-CCh estimates in regulatory impact analysis.  With
the release of the response to comments, the interagency working group announced plans to
obtain expert independent advice from the National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and
Medicine to ensure that the SC-CCh estimates continue to reflect the best available scientific and
economic information on climate change.  The Academies review will be informed by the public
comments received and focus on the technical merits and challenges of potential approaches to
improving the SC-CO2 estimates in future updates.

       Concurrent with OMB's publication of the response to comments on SC-CO2 and
announcement of the Academies process,  OMB posted a revised TSD that includes two minor
technical corrections to the current estimates.18  One technical correction addressed an
inadvertent omission of climate change damages in the last year of analysis (2300) in one model
and the second addressed a minor indexing error in another model. On average the revised SC-
CO2 estimates are one dollar less than the  mean SC-CO2 estimates reported in the November
2013 TSD.  The change in the estimates associated with the 95th percentile estimates when using
a 3% discount rate is slightly larger, as those estimates are heavily influenced by the results from
the model that was affected by the indexing error.

       The four SC-CO2 estimates are: $15, $50, $73, and $150 per metric ton of CO2 emissions
in the year 2025 (2012 dollars).19  The first three values are based on the average SC-CO2 from
the three lAMs, at discount rates of 5, 3, and 2.5 percent,  respectively. Estimates of the SC-CO2
for several discount rates are included because the literature shows that the SC-CO2 is sensitive
to assumptions about the  discount rate, and because no consensus exists on the appropriate rate
18 See https://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/oira/social-cost-of-carbon for the response to comments, the blog post
   announcing the Academies' process, and the current TSD.
19 The TSDs present SC-CO2 in $2007. The estimates were adjusted to 2012$ using the GDP Implicit Price
   Deflator. Also available at: http://www.gpo.gov/fdsys/pkg/iECONI-2013-02/pdf/ECONI-2013-02-Pg3.pdf. The
   SC-CO2 values have been rounded to two significant digits. Unrounded numbers from the 2013 SCC TSD were
   adjusted to 2012$ and used to calculate the CO2 benefits.

                                           4-7

-------
to use in an intergenerational context (where costs and benefits are incurred by different
generations). The fourth value is the 95th percentile of the SC-CCh across all three models at a
3% discount rate. It is included to represent higher-than-expected impacts from temperature
change further out in the tails of the SC-CO2 distribution. The SC-CO2 increases over time
because future emissions are expected to produce larger incremental damages as economies grow
and physical and economic systems become more stressed in response to greater climate change.

       A challenge particularly relevant to this proposal  is that the IWG did not estimate the
social costs of non-CCh GHG emissions at the time the SC-CCh estimates were developed. One
alternative approach to value methane impacts is to use the global warming potential (GWP) to
convert the emissions to CO2 equivalents which are then valued using the SC-CO2 estimates.

       The GWP measures the cumulative radiative forcing from a perturbation of a non-CCh
GHG relative to a perturbation  of CO2 over a fixed time horizon, often 100 years. The GWP
mainly reflects differences in the radiative efficiency of gases and differences in their
atmospheric lifetimes. While the GWP is a simple, transparent, and well-established metric for
assessing the relative impacts of non-CCh emissions compared to CO2 on a purely physical basis,
there are several well-documented limitations in using it  to value non-CCh GHG benefits, as
discussed in the 2010 SCC TSD and previous rulemakings (e.g., EPA 2012b, 2012d).20 In
particular, several recent studies found that GWP-weighted benefit estimates for methane are
likely to be lower than the estimates derived using directly modeled social cost estimates for
these gases. Gas comparison metrics, such as the GWP, are designed to measure the impact of
non-CO2 GHG emissions relative to CO2 at a specific point along the pathway from emissions to
monetized damages (depicted in Figure 4-1), and this point may differ across measures.
 1 See also Reilly and Richards 1993; Schmalensee 1993; Fankhauser 1994; Marten and Newbold 2012.

                                           4-8

-------
1. niKMCKis


Atmospheric
Concentration


Riidiirti'i'e
Forcing
k,

i m (i.i ft*,


f nvironiTiental
and Socio-
Econornic
Impatti


Moru'luccl
DdlflJgt1!.
Figure 4-1  Path from GHG Emissions to Monetized Damages (Source: Marten et al.,
2014)
       The GWP is not ideally suited for use in benefit-cost analyses to approximate the social
cost of non-CO2 GHGs because it ignores important nonlinear relationships beyond radiative
forcing in the chain between emissions and damages. These can become relevant because gases
have different lifetimes and the SC-CCh takes into account the fact that marginal damages from
an increase in temperature are a function of existing temperature levels. Another limitation of gas
comparison metrics for this purpose is that some environmental and socioeconomic impacts are
not linked to all of the gases under consideration, or radiative forcing for that matter, and will
therefore be incorrectly allocated. For example, the economic impacts associated with increased
agricultural productivity due to higher atmospheric CO2 concentrations included in the SC-CO2
would be incorrectly allocated to methane emissions with the GWP-based valuation approach.

       Also of concern, is the fact that the assumptions made in estimating the GWP are not
consistent with the assumptions underlying SC-CCh estimates in general, and the SC-CCh
estimates developed by the IWG specifically. For example, the 100 year time horizon usually
used in estimating the GWP is less than the 300 year horizon the IWG used in developing the
SC-CO2 estimates. The GWP approach also treats all impacts within the time horizon equally,
independent of the time at which they occur. This is inconsistent with the role of discounting in
economic analysis, which accounts for a basic preference for earlier over later gains in utility and
expectations regarding future levels of economic growth. In the case of methane, which has a
relatively short lifetime compared to CO2, the temporal independence of the GWP could lead the
                                          4-9

-------
GWP approach to underestimate the SC-CH4 with a larger downward bias under higher discount
rates (Marten and Newbold 2012).21

       EPA sought public comments on the valuation of non-CCh GHG impacts in previous
rulemakings (EPA, 2012b; EPA, 2012d). In general, the commenters strongly encouraged EPA
to incorporate the monetized value of non-CCh GHG impacts into the benefit cost analysis,
however they noted the challenges associated with the GWP-approach, as discussed above, and
encouraged the use of directly-modeled estimates of the SC-CH4 to overcome those challenges.

       EPA had cited several researchers that had directly estimated the social cost of non-CCh
emissions using lAMs but noted that the number of such estimates was small compared to the
large number of SC-CO2 estimates available in the literature. EPA found considerable variation
among these published estimates in terms of the models and input assumptions they employ
(EPA, 2012b; EPA, 2012d). These studies differed in the emissions perturbation year, employed
a wide range of constant and variable discount rate specifications, and considered a range of
baseline socioeconomic and emissions scenarios that have been developed over the last 20 years.
Furthermore, at the time, none of the other published estimates of the social cost of non-CCh
GHG were consistent with the SC-CO2 estimates developed by the IWG, and most were likely
underestimates due to changes in the underlying science since their publication.

       Therefore, EPA concluded that the GWP approach would serve as an interim method of
analysis until directly modeled social cost estimates for non-CCh GHGs, consistent with the SC-
CO2 estimates developed by the IWG, were developed.  EPA presented GWP-weighted estimates
in sensitivity analyses rather than the main benefit-cost analyses.

       Since then, a paper by Marten et al. (2014) has provided the first set of published SC-CH4
estimates in the peer-reviewed literature that are consistent with the modeling assumptions
underlying the SC-CO2 estimates.22 Specifically, the estimation approach of Marten et al. used
21 We note that the truncation of the time period in the GWP calculation could lead to an overestimate of SC-CH4 for
   near term perturbation years in cases where the SC-CCh is based on a sufficiently low or steeply declining
   discount rate.
22 Marten et al. (2014) also provided the first set of SC-N2O estimates that are consistent with the assumptions
   underlying the SC-CCh estimates.

                                          4-10

-------
the same set of three lAMs, five socioeconomic and emissions scenarios, equilibrium climate
sensitivity distribution, three constant discount rates, and aggregation approach used by the IWG
to develop the SC-CCh estimates. The aggregation method involved distilling the 45 distributions
of the SC-CH4 produced for each emissions year into four estimates: the mean across all models
and scenarios using a 2.5 percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount rate, and the 95th percentile
of the pooled estimates from all models and scenarios using a 3 percent discount rate. The
atmospheric lifetime radiative efficacy of methane used by Marten et al. is based on the estimates
reported by the IPCC in their Fourth Assessment Report (AR4, 2007), including an adjustment in
the radiative efficacy of methane to account for its role as a precursor for tropospheric ozone and
stratospheric water. These values represent the same ones used by in the IPCC in AR4 for
calculating GWPs. At the time Marten et al. developed their estimates of the SC-CH4, AR4 was
the latest assessment report by the IPCC. The IPCC updates GWP estimates with each new
assessment, and in the latest assessment, AR5, the latest estimate of the methane GWP ranged
from 28-36,  compared to a GWP of 25 in AR4. The updated values reflect a number of changes:
changes in the lifetime and radiative efficiency estimates for CO2, changes in the lifetime
estimate for methane,  and changes in the correction factor applied to methane's GWP to reflect
the effect of methane emissions on other climatically important substances such as tropospheric
ozone and stratospheric water vapor. In addition, the range presented in the latest IPCC report
reflects different choices  regarding whether to account for how biogenic and fossil methane have
different carbon cycle effects, and for whether to account for climate feedbacks on the carbon
cycle for both methane and carbon dioxide (rather than just for carbon dioxide as was done in
AR4).23'24
23 Climate Change 2013: The Physical Science Basis. Contribution of Working Group I to the Fifth Assessment
  Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [Stacker, T.F., D. Qin, G.-K. Plattner, M. Tignor,
  S.K. Allen, J. Boschung, A. Nauels, Y. Xia, V. Bex and P.M. Midgley (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press,
  Cambridge, United Kingdom and New York, NY, USA.
24 Note that this proposal uses a GWP value for methane of 25 for CCh equivalency calculations, consistent with the
  GHG emissions inventories and the IPCC Fourth Assessment Report.
                                          4-11

-------
       Marten et al. (2014) discuss these estimates (SC-CH4 estimates presented below in Table
4-2), and compare them with other recent estimates in the literature.25 The authors noted that a
direct comparison of their estimates with all of the other published estimates is difficult, given
the differences in the models and socioeconomic and emissions scenarios, but results from three
relatively recent studies offer a better basis for comparison (see Hope (2006), Waldhoff et al.
(2014), Marten and Newbold (2012)). Marten et al. found that in general the SC-CH4 estimates
from their 2014 paper are higher than previous estimates. The  higher SC-CH4 estimates are
partially driven by the higher effective radiative forcing due to the inclusion of indirect effects
from methane emissions in their modeling. Marten et al., similar to other recent studies, also find
that their directly modeled SC-CH4 estimates are higher than the GWP-weighted estimates.
More detailed discussion of the SC-CH4 estimation methodology, results and a comparison to
other published estimates can be found in Marten et al.

Table 4-2  Social Cost of CH4, 2012 - 2050a [in 2012$ per metric ton] (Source: Marten et
al., 2014b)
Year
2012
2015
2020
2025
2030
2035
2040
2045
2050
5%
Average
$430
$490
$580
$700
$820
$970
$1,100
$1,300
$1,400
3%
Average
$1,000
$1,100
$1,300
$1,500
$1,700
$1,900
$2,200
$2,500
$2,700
SC-CH4
2.5%
Average
$1,400
$1,500
$1,700
$1,900
$2,200
$2,500
$2,800
$3,000
$3,300
3%
95th percentile
$2,800
$3,000
$3,500
$4,000
$4,500
$5,300
$5,900
$6,600
$7,200
a The values are emissions-year specific and are defined in real terms, i.e., adjusted for inflation using the GDP
implicit price deflator.
b The estimates in this table have been adjusted to reflect the minor technical corrections to the SC-CCh estimates
described above. See Marten et al. (2015) for more details.
 ' Marten et al. (2014) estimates are presented in 2007 dollars. These estimates were adjusted for inflation using
   National Income and Product Accounts Tables, Table 1.1.9, Implicit Price Deflators for Gross Domestic Product
   (US Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis), http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm
   Accessed 3/3/15.
                                            4-12

-------
       The application of directly modeled estimates from Marten et al. (2014) to benefit-cost
analysis of a regulatory action is analogous to the use of the SC-CCh estimates. Specifically, the
SC-CH4 estimates in Table 4-2 are used to monetize the benefits of reductions in methane
emissions expected as a result of the proposed rulemaking. Forecast changes in methane
emissions in a given year, expected as a result of the proposed regulatory action, are multiplied
by the SC-CH4 estimate for that year. To obtain a present value estimate, the monetized stream
of future non-CO2 benefits are discounted back to the analysis year using the same discount rate
used to estimate the social cost of the non-CCh GHG emission changes. In addition, the
limitations for the SC-CO2 estimates discussed above likewise apply to the SC-CH4 estimates,
given the consistency in the methodology.

       EPA recently conducted a peer review of the application of the Marten et al. (2014) non-
CO2 social cost estimates in regulatory analysis and received responses that supported this
application. Three reviewers considered seven charge questions that covered issues such as the
EPA's interpretation of the Marten et al. estimates, the consistency of the estimates with the  SC-
CO2 estimates, EPA's characterization of the limits of the GWP-approach to value non-CCh
GHG impacts, and the appropriateness of using the Marten et al. estimates in regulatory impact
analyses. The reviewers agreed with EPA's interpretation of Marten et al.'s estimates; generally
found the estimates to be consistent with the SC-CCh estimates; and concurred with the
limitations of the GWP approach, finding directly modeled estimates to be more appropriate.
While outside of the scope of the review, the reviewers briefly considered the limitations in the
SC-CO2 methodology (e.g., those discussed earlier in this section) and noted that because the
SC-CO2 and SC-CH4 methodologies are similar, the limitations also apply to the resulting SC-
CH4 estimates. Two of the reviewers concluded that use in RIAs of the SC-CH4 estimates
developed by Marten  et al. and published in the peer-reviewed literature is appropriate, provided
that the Agency discuss the limitations, similar to the discussion provided for SC-CO2 and other
economic analyses. All three reviewers encouraged continued improvements in the SC-CO2
estimates and suggested that as those improvements are realized they should also be reflected in
the SC-CH4 estimates, with one reviewer suggesting the SC-CH4 estimates lag this process. EPA
supports continued improvement in the SC-CCh  estimates developed by the U.S. government and
                                         4-13

-------
agrees that improvements in the SC-CO2 estimates should also be reflected in the SC-CH4
estimates. The fact that the reviewers agree that the SC-CH4 estimates are generally consistent
with the SC-CO2 estimates that are recommended by OMB's guidance on valuing CO2 emissions
reductions leads EPA to conclude that use of the SC-CH4 estimates is an analytical improvement
over excluding methane emissions from the monetized portion of the benefit cost analysis.

       In light of the favorable peer review and past comments urging EPA to value non-CCh
GHG impacts in its rulemakings, the Agency has used the Marten et al. (2014) SC-CH4 estimates
to value methane impacts expected from this proposed rulemaking and has included those
benefits in the main benefits analysis. EPA seeks comments on the use of these directly modeled
estimates, from the peer-reviewed literature, for the social cost of non-CCh  GHG.

       The methane benefits calculated using Marten et al.  (2014) are presented below in Table
4-3 for 2025.  Applying this approach to the methane reductions estimated for this proposal, the
2025 methane benefits vary by discount rate and range from about $310 million to approximately
$1.7 billion; for the proposed option, the mean SC-CH4 at the 3% discount rate results in an
estimate of about $660 million in 2025.

Table 4-3  Estimated Global Benefits of CH4 Reductions in 2025* (in millions, 2012$)





Alternative Option 2.5/40
Proposed Option 2.5/34
Alternative Option 2.0/34
Million
metric

tonnes of
CH4
reduced

0.27
0.44
0.48
Million
metric
tonnes of
CO2-
equivalent
reduced
6.8
11
12
Discount rate and statistic

5%
(average)

$190
$310
$340

3%
(average)

$410
$660
$720

2.5%
(average)

$530
$850
$930

3% (95th
percentile)

$1,100
$1,700
$1,900
 *The SC-CH4 values are dollar-year and emissions-year specific. SC-CH4 values represent only a partial
 accounting of climate impacts.
       While the vast majority of this proposal's climate-related benefits are associated with
methane reductions, additional climate-related benefits are expected from the proposal's
secondary air impacts, specifically, a net reduction in CO2 emissions due to reduced demand for
                                         4-14

-------
electricity from the grid as landfills generate electricity from landfill gas.26 These benefits are
presented in Table 4-4 below. Monetizing the net CO2 reductions with the SC-CO2 estimates
described in this section yields benefits that vary by discount rate and range from about $3.6
million to approximately $36 million in 2025. For the proposed option, the mean SC-CO2 at the
3% discount rate results in an estimate of about  $12 million in 2025, which is about 2 percent of
the estimated methane benefits in 2025 (average SC-CH4, 3 percent discount rate).

Table 4-4  Estimated Global Benefits of Net COi Reductions in 2025* (in millions, 2012$)
, , A . A , Discount rate and statistic
Metric tonnes ol net


Alternative Option 2.5/40
Proposed Option 2.5/34
Alternative Option 2.0/34
CC>2 reduced

102,000
238,000
238,000
5%
(average)
$1.5
$3.6
$3.6
3%
(average)
$5.0
$12
$12
2.5%
(average)
$7.5
$18
$18
3% (95th
percentile)
$15
$36
$36
 *The SC-CCh values are dollar-year and emissions-year specific. SC-CCh values represent only a partial
 accounting of climate impacts.
       Finally, in addition to the CO2 impacts discussed above, there is a small increase in CO2
emissions resulting from flaring of methane in response to this rule. We are not estimating the
monetized disbenefits of these secondary emissions of CO2 because much of the methane that
would have been released in the absence of the flare would have eventually oxidized into CO2 in
the atmosphere. Note that the CO2 produced from the methane oxidizing in the atmosphere is not
included in the calculation of the SC-CFU.

       However, EPA does recognize that because the growth rate of the SC-CCh estimates are
lower than their associated discount rates, the estimated impact of CCh produced in the future
from oxidized methane would be less than the estimated impact of CO2 released immediately
from flaring, which would imply a small disbenefit associated with flaring.  Assuming an average
methane oxidation period of 8.7 years, consistent with the lifetime used in IPCC AR4, the
26 The reduced demand for electricity from the grid more than offsets the additional energy demand required to
   operate the control system and the by-product emissions from the combustion of LFG.
                                          4-15

-------
disbenefits associated with destroying one metric ton of methane and releasing the CO2
emissions in 2020 instead of being released in the future via the methane oxidation process is
estimated to be $5 to $25 per metric ton CH4 depending on the SC-CO2 value or 0.7 percent to
0.9 percent of the SC-CH4 estimates per metric ton for 2020. The analogous estimates for 2025
are $7 to $34 per metric ton CH4 or 0.8 percent to 1.0 percent of the SC-CH4 estimates per metric
ton for 2025.27 While EPA is not accounting for the CO2 disbenefits at this time, we request
comment on the appropriateness of the monetization of such impacts using the SC-CO2 and
aspects of the calculation.

4.2.2  Methane as an ozone precursor

       This rulemaking would reduce emissions of methane, a GHG and also a precursor to
ozone. In remote areas, methane is a dominant precursor to tropospheric ozone formation (EPA,
2013). Approximately 40% of the global annual mean ozone increase since preindustrial times is
believed to be due to anthropogenic methane (HTAP, 2010). Projections of future emissions also
indicate that methane is likely to be a key contributor to ozone concentrations in the future
(HTAP, 2010).  Unlike NOx and VOC, which affect ozone concentrations regionally and at
hourly time scales, methane emissions affect ozone concentrations globally and on decadal time
scales given methane's relatively long atmospheric lifetime (HTAP, 2010).  Reducing methane
emissions, therefore, can reduce global background ozone concentrations, human exposure to
ozone, and the incidence of ozone-related health effects (West et al., 2006, Anenberg et al., 2009,
Sarofim et al., 2015).  These benefits are global and occur in both urban and rural areas.
Reductions in background ozone concentrations can also have benefits for agriculture and
ecosystems (UNEP/WMO, 2011). Studies show that controlling methane emissions can reduce
global ozone concentrations and climate  change simultaneously, but controlling other shorter-
lived ozone precursors such as NOx, carbon monoxide, or non-methane VOC has larger local
 ' To calculate the disbenefits associated the complete destruction of a ton of CH4 through flaring, EPA took the
   difference between the SC-CCh at the time of the flaring and in 8.7 years and discounted that value to the time of
   the flaring using the same discount rate as used to estimate the SC-CCh. This value was then scaled by 44/16 to
   account for the relative mass of carbon contained in a ton of CH4 versus a ton of COa. The value of the SC-CCh
   8.7 years after flaring was estimated by linearly interpolating between the annual SC-CCh estimates reported in
   the TSD and inflated to 2012 dollars.
                                           4-16

-------
health benefits from greater reductions in local ozone concentrations (West and Fiore, 2005;
West et al., 2006; Fiore et al. 2008; Dentener et al., 2005; Shindell et al., 2005, 2012;
UNEP/WMO, 2011). The health, welfare, and climate effects associated with ozone are
described in the preceding sections. Without air quality modeling, we are unable to estimate the
effect that reducing methane will have on ozone concentrations at particular locations. However,
the global monetized benefit of ozone reduction due to methane mitigation have been estimated
in several studies (Anenberg et al., 2012; Shindell et al., 2012).

       Recently, a paper was published  in the peer-reviewed scientific literature that presented a
range of estimates of the monetized ozone-related mortality benefits of reducing methane
emissions (Sarofim et al. 2015).  For example, under their base case assumptions using a 3%
discount rate, Sarofim et al. find global ozone-related mortality benefits of methane emissions
reductions to be $790 per tonne of methane in 2020, with 10.6%, or $80, of this amount resulting
from mortality reductions in the United States.  The methodology used in this study is consistent
in some (but not all) aspects with the modeling underlying the SC-CO2 and  SC-CH4 estimates
discussed above, and required a number of additional assumptions such as baseline mortality
rates and mortality response to ozone concentrations.  The Sarofim et al. (2015) study  may have
implications for this benefits analysis as it provides a potential approach to estimating the ozone
related mortality benefits resulting from  the methane reductions expected from this proposed
rulemaking. The EPA requests comment on Sarofim et al.'s approach to estimating the ozone
related mortality benefits of methane emissions reductions, including technical considerations in
applying  their methodology to this regulatory impact analysis.

4.2.3   Combined climate and ozone effects of methane

       A recent United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) assessment provided a
comprehensive analysis of the health, climate, and agricultural benefits of measures to reduce
methane, as well as black  carbon, a component of fine particulate matter that absorbs radiation
(UNEP/WMO, 2011; Shindell et al.,  2012). The UNEP assessment found that while reducing
longer-lived GHGs such as CO2 is necessary to protect against long-term climate change,
reducing  global methane and black carbon emissions would have global health benefits by
reducing  exposure to ozone and PIVh.s as well as potentially slowing the rate of climate change
                                          4-17

-------
within the first half of this century. Relative to a business as usual reference scenario,
implementing methane mitigation measures that achieve approximately 40% reductions in global
methane emissions were estimated to avoid approximately 0.3°C globally averaged warming in
2050 (including the impacts of both methane itself and subsequently formed ozone) and 47,000
ozone-related premature deaths and 27 million metric tons of ozone-related crop yield losses
globally in 2030 (Shindell et al., 2012). These benefits, including global climate impacts of
methane and resulting ozone changes, and global ozone-related health and agricultural impacts,
were valued at $700 to $5,000 per metric ton.28 While monetized per-ton benefits of the climate,
health, and agriculture impacts of methane mitigation have been estimated, there has not yet been
a similar monetization of the parallel impacts on broader ecosystems.

4.3  VOC as a PMi.s precursor

       This rulemaking would reduce emissions of VOC, which are a precursor to PIVb.s. Most
VOC emitted are oxidized to carbon dioxide (CO2) rather than to PM, but a portion of VOC
emission contributes to ambient PlVb.5 levels as organic carbon aerosols (EPA, 2009a).
Therefore, reducing these emissions would reduce PIVb.s formation, human exposure to PIVb.s,
and the incidence of PIVh.s-related health effects.  However,  we have not quantified the PlVb.s-
related benefits in this analysis. Analysis of organic carbon measurements suggest only a
fraction of secondarily formed organic carbon aerosols are of anthropogenic origin. The current
state of the science of secondary organic carbon aerosol formation indicates that anthropogenic
VOC contribution to secondary organic carbon aerosol is often lower than the biogenic (natural)
contribution.  Given that a fraction of secondarily formed organic carbon aerosols is from
anthropogenic VOC emissions and the extremely small amount of VOC emissions from this
sector relative to the entire VOC inventory it is unlikely this sector has a large contribution to
 ! Benefit per ton values derived from Shindell et al. (2012) cannot be directly compared to, nor are they additive
  with, the ozone health benefit-per-ton estimates for the U.S. reported in Section 4.4.1, since they include climate
  and agricultural impacts, are calculated for global rather than U.S. impacts, and use different assumptions for the
  value of a statistical life. Similarly, these values cannot be compared to, nor are they additive with, the methane
  climate valuation estimates in Section 4.2.1 since they include health and agricultural benefits and use different
  assumptions for the Social Cost of Carbon.

                                            4-18

-------
ambient secondary organic carbon aerosols. Photochemical models typically estimate secondary
organic carbon from anthropogenic VOC emissions to be less than 0.1 |ig/m3.

       Data resources and methodological limitations prevented EPA from monetizing the
benefits of reducing VOCs. We were unable to perform air quality modeling for this rule to
quantify the PIVb.s benefits associated with reducing VOC emissions. Due to the high degree of
variability in the responsiveness of PIVb.s formation to VOC emission reductions, we are unable
to estimate the effect that reducing VOC will have on ambient PIVb.s levels without air quality
modeling. However, we provide the discussion below for context regarding findings from
previous modeling.

4.3.1   PMi.s health effects and valuation

       Reducing VOC emissions would reduce PM2.5 formation, human exposure, and the
incidence of PIVh.s-related health effects. Reducing exposure to PIVb.s is associated with
significant human health benefits, including avoiding mortality and respiratory morbidity.
Researchers have associated PIVb.s exposure with adverse health effects in numerous
lexicological,  clinical and epidemiological studies (EPA, 2009a). When adequate data and
resources are available, EPA generally quantifies several health effects associated with exposure
to PM2.5 (e.g.,  EPA, 201 Id).  These health effects include premature mortality for adults and
infants, cardiovascular morbidity such as heart attacks, hospital admissions, and respiratory
morbidity such as asthma attacks, acute and chronic bronchitis, hospital and ER visits, work loss
days, restricted activity days, and respiratory symptoms. Although EPA has not quantified these
effects in previous benefits analyses, the scientific literature suggests that exposure to PIVb.s is
also associated with adverse effects on birth weight, pre-term births, pulmonary function, other
cardiovascular effects, and other respiratory effects (EPA, 2009a).

       When EPA quantifies PIVh.s-related benefits, the Agency assumes that all fine particles,
regardless of their chemical composition, are equally potent in causing premature mortality
because the scientific evidence is not yet sufficient to allow differentiation of effect estimates by
particle type (EPA, 2009a).  Based on our review of the current body of scientific literature, EPA
estimates PM-related mortality without applying an assumed concentration threshold.  This
                                           4-19

-------
decision is supported by the data, which are quite consistent in showing effects down to the
lowest measured levels of PM2.5 in the underlying epidemiology studies.

       Previous studies have estimated the monetized benefits-per-ton of reducing VOC
emissions associated with the effect that those emissions have on ambient PIVb.s levels and the
health effects associated with PIVh.s exposure (Fann, Fulcher, and Hubbell, 2009), and these
estimates can provide useful context for this rulemaking. Using the estimates in Fann, Fulcher,
and Hubbell (2009), the monetized benefit-per-ton of reducing VOC emissions in nine urban
areas of the U.S. ranges from $560 in Seattle, WA to $5,700 in San Joaquin, CA, with a national
average of $2,400. These estimates assume a 50 percent reduction in VOC, the Laden et al.
(2006) mortality function (based on the Harvard Six Cities study, a large cohort epidemiology
study in the Eastern U.S.), an analysis year of 2015, a 3% discount rate, and 2006$.

        Additional benefit-per-ton estimates are available from this dataset using alternate
assumptions regarding the relationship between PIVb.s exposure and premature mortality from
empirical studies and supplied by experts (e.g., Pope et al., 2002; Laden et al.,  2006; Roman et
al., 2008). EPA generally presents a range of benefits estimates derived from the American
Cancer Society cohort (e.g., Pope et al., 2002; Krewski et al., 2009) to the Harvard Six Cities
cohort (e.g., Laden et al., 2006; Lepuele et al., 2012) because the studies are both well-designed
and extensively peer reviewed, and EPA provides the benefit estimates derived from expert
opinions in Roman et al. (2008) as a characterization of uncertainty. As shown in Table 4-5, the
range of VOC benefits that reflects the range of epidemiology studies and the range of the urban
areas is $300 to $7,500 per ton of VOC reduced (2012$).29 Since these estimates were presented
in the 2012 Oil and Gas NSPS RIA (EPA, 2012b), we updated our methods to apply more recent
epidemiological studies for these cohorts  (i.e., Krewski et al., 2009; Lepeule et al., 2012) as well
as additional updates to the morbidity studies and population data.30 Because these updates
29 We also converted the estimates from Fann, Fulcher, and Hubbell (2009) to 2012$ and applied EPA's current
   value of a statistical life (VSL) estimate. For more information regarding EPA's current VSL estimate, please see
   Section 5.6.5.1 of the RIA for the PM NAAQS RIA (EPA, 2012c). EPA continues to work to update its
   guidance on valuing mortality risk reductions.
30 For more information regarding these updates, please see Section 5.3 of the RIA for the final PM NAAQS (EPA,
   2012c).

                                           4-20

-------
would not lead to significant changes in the benefit-per-ton estimates for VOC, we have not
updated them here.

       While these ranges of benefit-per-ton estimates provide useful context, the geographic
distribution of VOC emissions from the MSW landfill sector are not consistent with emissions
modeled in Fann, Fulcher, and Hubbell (2009).  In addition, the benefit-per-ton estimates for
VOC emission reductions in that study are derived from total VOC emissions across all sectors.
Coupled with the larger uncertainties about the relationship between VOC emissions and PIVb.s,
these factors lead the EPA to conclude that the available VOC benefit per ton estimates are not
appropriate to calculate monetized benefits of this rule, even as a bounding exercise.
                                          4-21

-------
Table 4-5  Monetized Benefits-per-Ton Estimates for VOC based on Previous Modeling in 2015 (2012$)
       Area
Pope et al.    Laden et al.  Expert Expert  Expert  Expert Expert Expert  Expert  Expert Expert Expert  Expert  Expert
  (2002)         (2006)        ABCDEFGHI       JKL
Atlanta
Chicago
Dallas
Denver
NYC/ Philadelphia
Phoenix
Salt Lake
San Joaquin
Seattle
National average
$660
$1,600
$320
$770
$2,300
$1,100
$1,400
$3,100
$300
$1,300
$1,600
$4,000
$790
$1,900
$5,600
$2,700
$3,300
$7,500
$730
$3,200
$1,700
$4,200
$830
$2,000
$5,900
$2,800
$3,500
$7,900
$770
$3,400
$1,300
$3,300
$650
$1,500
$4,600
$2,200
$2,700
$6,100
$570
$2,600
$1,300
$3,200
$630
$1,500
$4,500
$2,100
$2,700
$6,000
$590
$2,600
$920
$2,300
$450
$1,100
$3,200
$1,500
$1,900
$4,300
$420
$1,800
$2,100
$5,300
$1,000
$2,400
$7,300
$3,500
$4,400
$9,700
$950
$4,200
$1,200
$3,000
$580
$1,400
$4,100
$2,000
$2,500
$5,500
$540
$2,300
$780
$1,900
$380
$910
$2,700
$1,300
$1,600
$3,600
$350
$1,500
$980
$2,400
$480
$1,100
$3,400
$1,600
$2,000
$4,500
$440
$1,900
$1,300
$3,200
$630
$1,500
$4,500
$2,100
$2,700
$6,000
$580
$2,500
$1,000
$2,600
$510
$1,200
$3,600
$1,700
$2,200
$4,900
$470
$2,100
$260
$640
$130
$300
$890
$420
$570
$1,400
$120
$520
$1,000
$2,500
$490
$910
$3,300
$1,600
$2,100
$4,600
$350
$1,900
 : These estimates assumed a 50 percent reduction in VOC emissions, an analysis year of 2015, and a 3 percent discount rate.  All estimates are rounded to two
  significant digits. These estimates have been adjusted from Farm, Fulcher, and Hubbell (2009) to reflect a more recent currency year and EPA's current VSL
  estimate. However, these estimates have not been updated to reflect recent epidemiological studies for mortality studies, morbidity studies, or population data.
  Using a discount rate of 7 percent, the benefit-per-ton estimates would be approximately 9 percent lower. Assuming a 75 percent reduction in VOC emissions
  would increase the benefit-per-ton estimates by approximately 4 percent to 52 percent. Assuming a 25 percent reduction in VOC emissions would decrease the
  benefit-per-ton estimates by 5 percent to 52 percent. EPA generally presents a range of benefits estimates derived from the expert functions from Roman et al.
  (2008) as a characterization of uncertainty.
                                                                   4-22

-------
4.3.2   Visibility Effects

       Reducing secondary formation of PIVb.s from VOC emissions would improve visibility
throughout the U.S. Fine particles with significant light-extinction efficiencies include sulfates,
nitrates, organic carbon, elemental carbon, and soil (Sisler, 1996). Suspended particles and gases
degrade visibility by scattering and absorbing light. Higher visibility impairment levels in the
East are due to generally higher concentrations of fine particles, particularly sulfates, and higher
average relative humidity levels.  Visibility has direct significance to people's enjoyment of daily
activities and their overall sense of wellbeing.  Good visibility increases the quality of life where
individuals live and work, and where they engage in recreational activities. Previous analyses
(EPA, 2006b; EPA, 201 Id; EPA, 201 la; EPA, 2012c) show that visibility benefits are a
significant welfare benefit category.  Without air quality modeling, we are unable to estimate
visibility related benefits, nor are we able to determine whether VOC emission reductions would
be likely to have a significant impact on visibility in urban areas or Class I areas.

4.4  VOC as an Ozone  Precursor

       This  rulemaking would reduce emissions of VOC, which are also precursors to secondary
formation of ozone. Ozone is not emitted directly into the air, but is created when its two
primary components, volatile organic compounds (VOC) and oxides of nitrogen (NOx), react in
the presence of sunlight.  In urban areas, compounds representing all classes of VOC and CO are
important compounds for ozone formation, but biogenic VOC emitted from vegetation tend to be
more important compounds in non-urban vegetated areas (EPA, 2013). Therefore, reducing
these emissions would reduce ozone formation, human exposure to ozone, and the incidence  of
ozone-related health effects.  However, we have not quantified the ozone-related benefits in this
analysis for several reasons.  First, previous rules have shown that the monetized benefits
associated with reducing ozone exposure are generally smaller than PM-related benefits, even
when ozone  is the pollutant targeted  for control (EPA, 2010a; EPA, 2014a). Second, the
complex non-linear chemistry of ozone formation introduces uncertainty to the development  and
application of a benefit-per-ton estimate, particularly for sectors with substantial new growth.
Third, the impact of reducing VOC emissions is spatially heterogeneous depending on local air
                                          4-23

-------
chemistry.  Urban areas with a high population concentration are often VOC-limited, which
means that ozone is most effectively reduced by lowering VOC. Rural areas and downwind
suburban areas are often NOx-limited, which means that ozone concentrations are most
effectively reduced by lowering NOx emissions, rather than lowering emissions of VOC.
Between these areas, ozone is relatively insensitive to marginal changes in both NOx and VOC.

       Due to data limitations, we did not perform air quality modeling for this rule needed to
quantify the ozone benefits associated with reducing VOC emissions. Due to the high degree of
variability in the responsiveness of ozone formation to VOC emission reductions and data
limitations regarding the location of the emissions reductions, we are unable to estimate the
effect that reducing VOC will have on ambient ozone concentrations without air quality
modeling.

4.4.1   Ozone health effects and valuation

       Reducing ambient ozone concentrations is associated with significant human health
benefits, including mortality and respiratory morbidity (EPA, 2010a). Researchers have
associated ozone exposure with adverse health effects in numerous lexicological, clinical and
epidemiological  studies (EPA, 2013). When adequate data and resources are available, EPA
generally quantifies several health effects associated with exposure to ozone (e.g., EPA, 2010a;
EPA,  201 la). These health effects include respiratory morbidity such as asthma attacks, hospital
and emergency department visits, school loss days, as well as premature mortality. The scientific
literature is also  suggestive that exposure to ozone is also associated with chronic respiratory
damage and premature aging of the lungs.

       In a recent EPA analysis, EPA estimated that reducing 15,000 tons of VOC from
industrial boilers resulted in $3.6 to $15 million (2008$) of monetized benefits from reduced
ozone exposure (EPA, 201 lb).31 After updating the currency year to 2012$, this implies a
benefit-per-ton for ozone of $260 to $1,070 per ton of VOC reduced. Since EPA conducted the
31 While EPA has estimated the ozone benefits for many scenarios, most of these scenarios also reduce NOx
   emissions, which make it difficult to isolate the benefits attributable to VOC reductions.
                                          4-24

-------
analysis of industrial boilers, EPA published the Integrated Science Assessment for Ozone (EPA,
2013), the Health Risk and Exposure Assessment for Ozone (EPA, 2014a), and the RIA for the
proposed Ozone NAAQS (EPA, 2014b). Therefore, the ozone mortality studies applied in the
boiler analysis, while current at that time, do not reflect the most updated literature available.
The selection of ozone mortality studies used to estimate benefits in RIAs was revisited in the
RIA for the proposed Ozone NAAQS. Applying the more recent studies would lead to benefit-
per-ton estimates for ozone within the range shown here. While these ranges of benefit-per-ton
estimates provide useful context, the geographic distribution of VOC emissions from the MSW
landfill sector are not consistent with emissions modeled in the boiler analysis. Therefore, we do
not believe that those estimates to provide useful estimates of the monetized benefits of this rule,
even as a bounding exercise.

4.4.2   Ozone vegetation effects

      Exposure to ozone has been associated with a wide array of vegetation and ecosystem
effects in the published literature (EPA, 2013a).  Sensitivity to ozone is highly variable across
species, with over 66 vegetation species identified as  "ozone-sensitive", many of which occur in
state and national parks and forests. These effects include those that damage or impair the
intended use of the plant or ecosystem.  Such effects are considered adverse to the public welfare
and can include reduced growth and/or biomass production in sensitive trees,  reduced yield and
quality of crops, visible foliar injury, species composition shift, and changes in ecosystems and
associated ecosystem services.

4.4.3   Ozone climate effects

       Ozone is a well-known short-lived climate forcing (SLCF) greenhouse gas (GHG) (EPA,
2006a).  Stratospheric ozone (the upper ozone layer) is beneficial because it protects life on Earth
from the sun's harmful ultraviolet (UV) radiation.  In contrast, tropospheric ozone (ozone in the
lower atmosphere) is a harmful air pollutant that adversely affects human health and the
environment and contributes significantly to regional  and global climate change.  Due to its short
atmospheric lifetime, tropospheric ozone concentrations exhibit large spatial and temporal
variability (EPA, 2009b). A recent United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) study
                                          4-25

-------
reports that the threefold increase in ground level ozone during the past 100 years makes it the
third most important contributor to human contributed climate change behind CO2 and methane.
This quantifiable influence of ground level ozone on climate leads to increases in global surface
temperature and changes in hydrological cycles.

4.5   Hazardous Air Pollutant (HAP) Benefits

      Even though emissions of air toxics from all sources in the U.S. declined by approximately
42 percent since 1990, the 2005 National-Scale Air Toxics Assessment (NAT A) predicts that
most Americans are exposed to ambient concentrations of air toxics at levels that have the
potential to cause adverse health effects (EPA, 201 lc).32  The levels of air toxics to which people
are exposed vary depending on where they live and work and the kinds of activities in which
they engage. In order to identify and  prioritize air toxics, emission source types and locations
that are of greatest potential concern,  the U.S. EPA conducts the NAT A.33 The most recent
NAT A was conducted for calendar year 2005 and was released in March 2011. NATA includes
four steps:

       1) Compiling  a national emissions inventory of air toxics emissions from outdoor sources
       2) Estimating  ambient concentrations of air toxics across the United States utilizing
       dispersion models
       3) Estimating  population exposures across the United States utilizing exposure models
       4) Characterizing potential public health risk due to inhalation of air toxics including both
       cancer and noncancer effects
32 The 2005 NATA is available on the Internet at http://www.epa.gov/ttn/atw/nata2005/.
33 The NATA modeling framework has a number of limitations that prevent its use as the sole basis for setting
   regulatory standards. These limitations and uncertainties are discussed on the 2005 NATA website. Even so,
   this modeling framework is very useful in identifying air toxic pollutants and sources of greatest concern, setting
   regulatory priorities, and informing the decision making process. U.S. EPA.  (2011) 2005 National-Scale Air
   Toxics Assessment, http://www.epa.gov/ttn/atw/nata2005/
                                            4-26

-------
       Based on the 2005 NAT A, EPA estimates that about 5 percent of census tracts
nationwide have increased cancer risks greater than 100 in a million. The average national
cancer risk is about 50 in a million.  Nationwide, the key pollutants that contribute most to the
overall cancer risks are formaldehyde and benzene.34'35  Secondary formation (e.g., formaldehyde
forming from other emitted pollutants) was the largest contributor to cancer risks, while
stationary, mobile and background sources  contribute almost equal portions of the remaining
cancer risk.

       Noncancer health effects can result from chronic,36 subchronic,37 or acute38 inhalation
exposures to air toxics, and include neurological, cardiovascular, liver, kidney, and respiratory
effects as well as effects on the immune and reproductive systems. According to the 2005
NAT A, about three-fourths of the U.S. population was exposed to an average chronic
concentration of air toxics that has the potential for adverse noncancer respiratory health effects.
Results from the 2005 NATA indicate that acrolein is the primary driver for noncancer
respiratory risk.

       Figure 4-2 and Figure 4-3 depict the estimated census tract-level carcinogenic risk and
noncancer respiratory hazard from the assessment. It is important to note that large reductions in
HAP emissions may not necessarily translate into significant reductions in health risk because
toxicity varies by pollutant, and exposures may or may not exceed levels of concern.  Thus, it is
important to account for the toxicity and exposure, as well as the mass of the targeted emissions.
34 Details on EPA's approach to characterization of cancer risks and uncertainties associated with the 2005 NATA
   risk estimates can be found at http://www.epa.gov/ttn/atw/natal999/riskbg.htmMZ2.
35 Details about the overall confidence of certainty ranking of the individual pieces of NATA assessments including
   both quantitative (e.g., model-to-monitor ratios) and qualitative (e.g., quality of data, review of emission
   inventories) judgments can be found at http://www.epa.gov/ttn/atw/nata/roy/pagel6.html.
36 Chronic exposure is defined in the glossary of the Integrated Risk Information System (IRIS) database
   (http://www.epa.gov/iris) as repeated exposure by the oral, dermal, or inhalation route for more than
   approximately 10% of the life span in humans (more than approximately 90 days to 2 years in typically used
   laboratory animal species).
37 Defined in the IRIS database as repeated exposure by the oral, dermal, or inhalation route for more than 30 days,
   up to approximately 10% of the life span in humans (more than 30 days up to approximately 90 days in typically
   used laboratory animal species).
38 Defined in the IRIS database as exposure by the oral, dermal, or inhalation route for 24 hours or less.
                                             4-27

-------
   Cancer Risk
   (in a million)
      1-25
   •• 25 - 50
   HI 5°-75
   •^ 75-100
   H =• 10°
      Zero Population Tracts
Figure 4-2  2005 NATA Model Estimated Census Tract Carcinogenic Risk from HAP
Exposure from Emissions of All Outdoor Sources (inclusive of Residental Wood Heaters)
based on the 2005 National Toxic Inventory.
                                          4-28

-------

   Total Respiratory
   Hazard Index
      o-1
      1-5
   ^H 5-10
   ^| 10-15
   H 15-20
   HI  •"•"•
      Zero Population Tracts
Figure 4-3  2005 NATA Model Estimated Census Tract Noncancer Risk from HAP
Exposure from Emissions of All Outdoor Sources (inclusive of Residental Wood Heaters)
based on the 2005 National Toxic Inventory

       Due to methodology and data limitations, we were unable to estimate the benefits
associated with the hazardous air pollutants that would be reduced as a result of this rule. In a
few previous analyses of the benefits of reductions in HAP, EPA has quantified the benefits of
potential reductions in the incidences of cancer and noncancer risk (e.g., EPA, 1995). In those
analyses, EPA relied on unit risk factors (URF) and reference concentrations (RfC) developed
through risk assessment procedures. The URF is a quantitative estimate of the carcinogenic
potency of a pollutant, often expressed as the probability of contracting cancer from a 70-year
lifetime continuous exposure to a concentration of one |ig/m3 of a pollutant. These URFs are
designed to be conservative, and  as such, are more likely to represent the high end of the
distribution of risk rather than a best or most likely estimate of risk.
                                          4-29

-------
       An RfC is an estimate (with uncertainty spanning perhaps an order of magnitude) of a
continuous inhalation exposure to the human population (including sensitive subgroups) that is
likely to be without an appreciable risk of deleterious noncancer health effects during a lifetime.
As part of the second prospective analysis of the benefits and costs of the Clean Air Act (EPA,
201 la), EPA conducted a case study analysis of the health effects associated with reducing
exposure to benzene in Houston from implementation of the Clean Air Act (ffic, 2009). While
reviewing the draft report, EPA's Advisory Council on Clean Air Compliance Analysis
concluded that "the challenges for assessing progress in health improvement as a result of
reductions in emissions of hazardous air pollutants (HAP) are daunting...due to a lack of
exposure-response functions, uncertainties in emissions inventories and background levels, the
difficulty of extrapolating risk estimates to low doses and  the challenges of tracking health
progress for  diseases, such as cancer, that have long latency periods" (EPA-SAB, 2008).

       In 2009, EPA convened a workshop to address the inherent complexities, limitations, and
uncertainties in current methods to quantify the benefits of reducing HAP. Recommendations
from this workshop included identifying research priorities, focusing on susceptible and
vulnerable populations, and improving dose-response relationships (Gwinn et al., 2011).

       In summary, monetization of the benefits of reductions in cancer incidences requires
several important inputs, including central estimates of cancer risks, estimates of exposure to
carcinogenic HAP, and estimates of the value of an avoided case of cancer (fatal and non-fatal).
Due to methodology and data limitations, we did not attempt to monetize the health benefits of
reductions in HAP in this analysis. Instead, we provide a qualitative analysis of the health effects
associated with the HAP anticipated to be reduced by this rule.  EPA remains committed to
improving methods for estimating HAP benefits by continuing to explore additional concepts of
benefits, including changes in the distribution of risk.

       In the subsequent sections, we describe the health effects associated with the main HAP
of concern from the MSW landfill sector: benzene, ethylbenzene, toluene, and vinyl chloride.
This rule is anticipated to avoid or reduce 2,770 tons of NMOC per year. With the data
available, it was not possible to estimate the tons of each individual HAP that would be reduced.
                                          4-30

-------
Therefore, in addition to the reasons identified above, we cannot estimate the monetized benefits

associated with reducing HAP emissions for this rule.


4.5.1  Benzene


       The EPA's IRIS database lists benzene as a known human carcinogen (causing leukemia)
by all routes of exposure, and concludes that exposure is associated with additional health effects,
including genetic changes in both humans and animals and increased proliferation of bone marrow
cells in mice.39'40'41 EPA states in its IRIS database that data indicate a causal relationship between
benzene exposure and acute lymphocyte leukemia and suggest a relationship between benzene
exposure and chronic non-lymphocytic leukemia and chronic lymphocyte leukemia. The IARC
has determined that benzene is a human carcinogen and the U.S. Department of Health and Human
Services has characterized benzene as a known human carcinogen.42'43

       A number of adverse noncancer health effects including blood disorders, such as
preleukemia and aplastic anemia, have  also been associated with long-term exposure to
benzene.44'45
39 U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2000. Integrated Risk Information System File for Benzene.
   Research and Development, National Center for Environmental Assessment, Washington, DC. This material is
   available electronically at: http://www.epa.gov/iris/subst/0276.htm.
40 International Agency for Research on Cancer, IARC monographs on the evaluation of carcinogenic risk of
   chemicals to humans, Volume 29, Some industrial chemicals and dyestuffs, International Agency for Research
   on Cancer, World Health Organization, Lyon, France, p. 345-389, 1982.
41 Irons, R.D.; Stillman, W.S.; Colagiovanni, D.B.; Henry, V.A. (1992)  Synergistic action of the benzene metabolite
   hydroquinone on myelopoietic stimulating activity of granulocyte/macrophage colony-stimulating factor in vitro,
   Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. 89:3691-3695.
42 International Agency for Research on Cancer (IARC). 1987. Monographs on the evaluation of carcinogenic risk
   of chemicals to humans, Volume 29, Supplement 7, Some industrial chemicals and dyestuffs,  World Health
   Organization, Lyon, France.
43 U.S. Department of Health and Human Services National Toxicology Program 11th Report on  Carcinogens
   available at: http://ntp.niehs.nih.gov/go/16183 .
44 Aksoy, M. (1989). Hematotoxicity and carcinogenicity of benzene. Environ. Health Perspect. 82: 193-197.
45 Goldstein, B.D. (1988). Benzene toxicity. Occupational medicine. State of the Art Reviews. 3:  541-554.
                                             4-31

-------
4.5.2  Ethylbenzene

       Ethylbenzene is a major industrial chemical produced by alkylation of benzene. The pure
chemical is used almost exclusively for styrene production. It is also a constituent of crude
petroleum and is found in gasoline and diesel fuels.  Acute (short-term) exposure to ethylbenzene
in humans results in respiratory effects such as throat irritation and chest constriction, and
irritation of the eyes, and neurological effects such as dizziness.  Chronic (long-term) exposure
of humans to ethylbenzene may cause eye and lung irritation, with possible adverse effects on
the blood.  Animal  studies have reported effects on the blood, liver,  and kidneys and endocrine
system from chronic inhalation exposure to ethylbenzene. No information is available on the
developmental or reproductive effects of ethylbenzene in humans, but animal studies have
reported developmental effects, including birth defects in animals exposed via inhalation.
Studies in rodents reported increases in the percentage of animals with tumors of the nasal and
oral  cavities in male and female rats exposed to ethylbenzene via the oral route.46"47 The reports
of these studies lacked detailed information on the incidence of specific tumors, statistical
analysis, survival data, and information on historical controls, thus the results of these studies
were considered inconclusive by the International Agency for Research on Cancer (IARC, 2000)
and the National Toxicology Program (NTP).48'49  The NTP (1999) carried out a chronic
inhalation bioassay in mice and rats and found clear evidence of carcinogenic activity in male
rats and some evidence in female rats, based on increased incidences of renal tubule adenoma  or
carcinoma in male rats and renal tubule adenoma in females. NTP (1999) also noted increases in
46 Maltoni C, Conti B, Giuliano C and Belpoggi F, 1985. Experimental studies on benzene carcinogenicity at the
   Bologna Institute of Oncology: Current results and ongoing research. Am J IndMed 7:415-446.
47 Maltoni C, Ciliberti A, Pinto C, Soffritti M, Belpoggi F and Menarini L, 1997. Results of long-term experimental
   carcinogenicity studies of the effects of gasoline, correlated fuels, and major gasoline aromatics on rats. Annals
   NYAcadSci 837:15-52.
^International Agency for Research on Cancer (IARC), 2000. Monographs on the Evaluation of Carcinogenic Risks
   to Humans. Some Industrial Chemicals. Vol. 77, p. 227-266. IARC, Lyon, France.
49 National Toxicology Program (NTP), 1999. Toxicology and Carcinogenesis Studies of Ethylbenzene (CAS No.
   100-41-4) inF344/N Rats and inB6C3Fl Mice (Inhalation Studies). Technical Report Series No. 466. NIH
   Publication No. 99-3956. U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, Public Health Service, National
   Institutes of Health. NTP, Research Triangle Park, NC.
                                            4-32

-------
the incidence of testicular adenoma in male rats. Increased incidences of lung

alveolar/bronchiolar adenoma or carcinoma were observed in male mice and liver hepatocellular

adenoma or carcinoma in female mice, which provided some evidence of carcinogenic activity in

male and female mice (NTP, 1999). IARC (2000) classified ethylbenzene as Group 2B, possibly

carcinogenic to humans, based on the NTP studies.


4.5.3  Toluene50


       Under the 2005 Guidelines for Carcinogen Risk Assessment, there is inadequate

information to assess the carcinogenic potential of toluene because studies of humans chronically

exposed to toluene are inconclusive, and toluene was not carcinogenic in adequate inhalation

cancer bioassays of rats and mice exposed for life.51'52'53  Increased incidences of mammary

cancer and leukemia were reported in a lifetime rat oral bioassay;54 however, this evidence was

considered equivocal since cancers were observed at the low dose tested (500mg/kg/day) but not

at the higher dose tested (800 mg/kg/day). In support of EPA's cancer classification, IARC has

classified toluene as Group 3 (not classifiable as to its carcinogenicity in humans) with a

supporting statement that there is inadequate evidence in humans and evidence suggesting a lack

of carcinogenicity of toluene in experimental animals.55
50 All health effects language for this section came from: U.S. EPA. 2005. "Full IRIS Summary for Toluene
   (CASRN 108-88-3)" Environmental Protection Agency, Integrated Risk Information System (IRIS), Office of
   Health and Environmental Assessment, Environmental Criteria and Assessment Office, Cincinnati, OH.
   Available on the Internet at .
51 CUT (Chemical Industry Institute of Toxicology). (1980) A twenty-four month inhalation toxicology study in
   Fischer-344 rats exposed to atmospheric toluene. Conducted by Industrial Bio-Test Laboratories, Inc., Decatur,
   IL, and Experimental Pathology Laboratories, Inc., Raleigh, NC, for CUT, Research Triangle Park, NC..
52 NTP (National Toxicology Program), 1990. Toxicology and carcinogenesis studies of toluene (CAS No. 108-88-
   3) in F344/N rats and B5C3F1 mice (inhalation studies). Public Health Service, U.S. Department of Health and
   Human Services; NTP TR 371. Available from: National Institute of Environmental Health Sciences, Research
   Triangle Park, NC.
53 Huff, J., 2003. Absence of carcinogenic activity in Fischer rats andB6C3Fl mice following 103-week inhalation
   exposures to toluene. Int J Occup Environ Health 9:138-146.
54 Maltoni, C; Ciliberti, A; Pinto, C; et al., 1997. Results of long-term experimental carcinogenicity studies of the
   effects of gasoline, correlated fuels, and major gasoline aromatics on rats. Ann NY Acad Sci 837:15-52.
55 IARC. (International Agency for Research on Cancer), 1999. IARC monographs on the evaluation of carcinogenic
   risks of chemicals to humans. Vol. 71, Part2. Re-evaluation of some organic chemicals, hydrazine and hydrogen
   peroxide. Lyon, France: International Agency for Research on Cancer, pp. 829-864.


                                             4-33

-------
       The central nervous system (CNS) is the primary target for toluene toxicity in both
humans and animals for acute and chronic exposures.  CNS dysfunction (which is often
reversible) and narcosis have been frequently observed in humans acutely exposed to low or
moderate levels of toluene by inhalation: symptoms include fatigue, sleepiness, headaches, and
nausea. Central nervous system depression has been reported to occur in chronic abusers
exposed to high levels of toluene.  Symptoms include ataxia, tremors, cerebral atrophy,
nystagmus (involuntary eye movements), and impaired speech, hearing, and vision.  Chronic
inhalation exposure of humans to toluene also causes irritation of the upper respiratory tract, eye
irritation, dizziness, headaches, and difficulty with sleep.

       Human studies have also reported developmental effects, such as CNS dysfunction,
attention deficits, and minor craniofacial and limb anomalies, in the children of women who
abused toluene during pregnancy.  A substantial database examining the effects of toluene in
subchronic and chronic occupationally exposed humans exists. The weight of evidence from
these studies indicates neurological effects (i.e., impaired color vision, impaired hearing,
decreased performance in neurobehavioral analysis, changes in motor and sensory nerve
conduction velocity, headache, and dizziness) as the most sensitive endpoint.

4.5.4  Vinyl Chloride56

       Most vinyl chloride is used to make polyvinyl chloride (PVC) plastic and vinyl products.
Acute (short-term) exposure to high levels of vinyl chloride in air has resulted in central nervous
system effects (CNS), such as dizziness, drowsiness, and headaches in humans. Chronic (long-
term) exposure to vinyl chloride through inhalation and oral exposure in humans has resulted in
liver damage. Cancer is a major concern from exposure to vinyl chloride via inhalation, as vinyl
chloride exposure has been shown to increase the risk of a rare form of liver cancer in humans.
56U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. Integrated Risk Information System (IRIS) on Vinyl Chloride. 2000.
 Available online at http://www.epa.gov/iris/subst/1001.htm.
                                          4-34

-------
EPA has classified vinyl chloride as a Group A, "human carcinogen ". IARC has classified vinyl
chloride as carcinogenic to humans (Group I).57

4.5.5   Other A ir Toxics

       In addition to the compounds described above, other air toxic compounds might be
affected by this rule. Information regarding the health effects of those compounds can be found
in EPA's IRIS  database.58

4.6    Alternative Years of Analysis

       While the EPA is assessing impacts in year 2025 as a representative year for the landfills
Emission Guidelines for existing MSW landfills, the quantity and composition of landfill gas
does change over the lifetime of a landfill, as discussed in Chapter 2. This section presents a
more complete picture of the climate benefits of the Emission Guidelines alternatives over time
by presenting results from the years 2020, 2030, and 2040.

       Table 4-6 presents the climate benefits of the alternatives in the 2020 snapshot year.

Table 4-6  Estimated Global Benefits of CH4 Reductions  in 2020*  (in millions, 2012$)
Million
metric
tonnes of
CH4
reduced
Alternative Option 2.5/40 0.24
Proposed Option 2.5/34 0.36
Alternative Option 2.0/34 0.40
Million Discount rate and statistic
metric
tonnes of
CQ _ 5% 3% 2.5% 3% (95th
equivalent (avera§e) (average) (average) percentile)
reduced
5.9 $140
9.0 $210
10.1 $240
$310
$460
$520
$410
$620
$700
$810
$1,200
$1,400
 *The SC-CH4 values are dollar-year and emissions-year specific. SC-CH4 values represent only a partial
 accounting of climate impacts.
57 International Agency for Research on Cancer (IARC). 2008. Monographs on the Evaluation of the Carcinogenic
  Risk of Chemicals for Humans. Vol. 97, pp311. Lyon, France: International Agency for Research on Cancer.
  Available online at http://monographs.iarc.fr/ENG/Monographs/vol97/index.php.
58U.S. EPA Integrated Risk Information System (IRIS) database is available at: www.epa.gov/iris
                                            4-35

-------
       Table 4-7 presents the climate benefits of the alternatives in the 2030 snapshot year.

Table 4-7  Estimated Global Benefits of CH4 Reductions in 2030* (in millions, 2012$)





Alternative Option 2.5/40
Proposed Option 2.5/34
Alternative Option 2.0/34
Million
metric

tonnes of
CH4
reduced

0.31
0.50
0.53
Million
metric
tonnes of
CO2-
equivalent
reduced
7.7
12
13
Discount rate and statistic

5%
(average)

$250
$410
$440

3%
(average)

$530
$860
$920

2.5%
(average)

$670
$1,100
$1,200

3% (95th
percentile)

$1,400
$2,300
$2,400
 *The SC-CH4 values are dollar-year and emissions-year specific.  SC-CH4 values represent only a partial
 accounting of climate impacts.
       Table 4-8 presents the climate benefits of the alternatives in the 2040 snapshot year.

Table 4-8  Estimated Global Benefits of CH4 Reductions in 2040* (in millions, 2012$)





Alternative Option 2.5/40
Proposed Option 2.5/34
Alternative Option 2.0/34
Million
metric

tonnes of
CH4
reduced

0.21
0.34
0.35
Million
metric
tonnes of
CO?-
equivalent
reduced
5.3
8.4
8.7
Discount rate and statistic

5%
(average)

$230
$360
$380

3%
(average)

$450
$720
$750

2.5%
(average)

$590
$940
$980

3% (95th
percentile)

$1,300
$2,000
$2,100
 *The SC-CH4 values are dollar-year and emissions-year specific.  SC-CH4 values represent only a partial
 accounting of climate impacts.

4.7   References

Anenberg, S.C., et al. 2009. "Intercontinental impacts of ozone pollution on human mortality,"
       Environ. Sci.  & Technol, 43, 6482-6487.

Anenberg SC, Schwartz J, Shindell D, et al. 2012. "Global air quality and health co-benefits of
       mitigating near-term climate change through methane and black carbon emission
       controls." Environ Health Perspect 120 (6):831.

Dentener, F., D. Stevenson, J. Cofala, R. Mechler, M. Amann, P. Bergamaschi, F. Raes, and R.
       Derwent. 2005. "The impact of air pollutant and methane emission controls on
       tropospheric ozone and radiative forcing: CTM calculations for the period  1990-2030,"
       Atmos. Chem. Phys., 5, 1731-1755.
                                           4-36

-------
Fankhauser, S. 1994. "The social costs of greenhouse gas emissions: an expected value
       approach." Energy Journal 15(2): 157-184.

Fann, N., C.M. Fulcher, BJ. Hubbell. 2009. "The influence of location, source, and emission
       type in estimates of the human health benefits of reducing a ton of air pollution." Air
       QualAtmos Health 2:169-176.

Fiore, A.M., JJ. West, L.W. Horowitz, V. Naik, and M.D. Schwarzkopf. 2008. "Characterizing
       the tropospheric ozone response to methane emission controls and the benefits to climate
       and air quality," J. Geophys. Res., 113, D08307, doi: 10.1029/2007JD009162

Forster, P. et al. 2007. Changes in Atmospheric Constituents and in Radiative Forcing. In:
       Climate Change 2007. The Physical Science Basis. Contribution of Working Group I to
       the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change
       [Solomon, S., D. Qin, M. Manning, Z. Chen, M. Marquis, K.B. Averyt, M. Tignor and
       H.L. Miller (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom and New
       York, NY, USA.

Gwinn, M.R., J. Craig, D.A. Axelrad, R. Cook, C. Dockins, N. Fann, R. Fegley, D.E. Guinnup,
       G. Helfand, B. Hubbell, S.L. Mazur, T. Palma, R.L. Smith, J. Vandenberg, and
       B. Sonawane. 2011. "Meeting report: Estimating the benefits of reducing hazardous air
       pollutants—summary of 2009 workshop and future considerations." Environ Health
       Perspect.  119(1): p. 125-30.

Hope, C. 2005. "The climate change benefits of reducing methane emissions." Climatic Change
       68(l):21-39.

Hope, C. and D. Newbery. 2006. "Calculating the Social Cost of Carbon" Forthcoming in
       Delivering a Low Carbon Electricity System: Technologies, Economics and Policy
       Editors: Michael Grubb,  Tooraj Jamasb and Michael G. Pollitt (University of Cambridge)
       Cambridge University Press, 
       Accessed March 30, 2015.

Industrial Economics, Inc (ffic).  2009. Section 812 Prospective Study of the Benefits and Costs of
       the Clean Air Act: Air Toxics Case Study—Health Benefits of Benzene Reductions in
       Houston, 1990-2020. Final Report, July 14, 2009.
       . Accessed March 30, 2015.

Interagency Working Group (IWG) on Social Cost of Carbon (SC-CCh). 2010. Technical
       Support Document: Social Cost of Carbon for Regulatory Impact Analysis Under
       Executive Order 12866. Docket ID EPA-HQ-OAR-2009-0472-114577. Participation by
       Council of Economic Advisers, Council on Environmental Quality, Department of
       Agriculture, Department of Commerce, Department of Energy, Department of
       Transportation, Environmental Protection Agency, National Economic Council, Office of
       Energy and Climate Change, Office of Management and Budget, Office of Science and
       Technology Policy, and Department of Treasury.
                                        4-37

-------
        Accessed March 31, 2015.

Interagency Working Group (IWG) on Social Cost of Carbon (SC-CCh). 2013.  Technical
       Support Document: Social Cost of Carbon for Regulatory Impact Analysis Under
       Executive Order 12866. Docket ID EPA-HQ-OAR-2013-0495. Participation by Council
       of Economic Advisers, Council on Environmental Quality, Department of Agriculture,
       Department of Commerce, Department of Energy, Department of Transportation,
       Domestic Policy Council, Environmental Protection Agency, National Economic
       Council, Office of Management and Budget, Office of Science and Technology Policy,
       and Department of Treasury.
        Accessed March 31, 2015.

Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). 2007. Climate Change 2007: Synthesis
       Report. Contribution of Working Groups I, II and III to the Fourth Assessment  Report of
       the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate  Change (AR4) [Core Writing Team, Pachauri,
       R.K and Reisinger, A. (eds.)]. IPCC, Geneva, Switzerland, 104 pp.
       .  Accessed March 30, 2015.

Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). 2007. IPCC Fourth Assessment Report:
       Climate Change 2007. Working Group II, Chapter 20  'Perspectives on Climate Change
       and Sustainability.'     Accessed March 30, 2011.

Kandlikar, M. 1995. "The relative role of trace gas emissions  in greenhouse abatement policies."
       Energy Policy 23(10): 879-883.

Krewski D.; M. Jerrett; R.T. Burnett; R. Ma; E. Hughes; Y. Shi, et al. 2009. Extended Follow-Up
       and Spatial Analysis of the American Cancer Society Study Linking Particulate Air
       Pollution and Mortality. HEI Research Report, 140, Health Effects Institute, Boston, MA.
       4-64.

Laden, F., J. Schwartz, F.E. Speizer, and D.W. Dockery. 2006. "Reduction in Fine Particulate
       Air Pollution and Mortality." American Journal of Respiratory and Critical Care
       Medicine 173:667-672.

Landers DH; Simonich SL; Jaffe DA; Geiser LH; Campbell DH; Schwindt AR; Schreck CB;
       Kent ML; Hafner WD; Taylor HE; Hageman KJ; Usenko S; Ackerman LK; Schrlau JE;
       Rose NL; Blett TF; Erway MM. 2008. The Fate, Transport and Ecological Impacts of
       Airborne Contaminants in Western National Parks (USA). EPA/600/R-07/138.  U.S.
       Environmental Protection Agency, Office of Research and Development, NHEERL,
       Western Ecology Division. Corvallis, Oregon.

Lepeule, J.; F. Laden; D. Dockery; J. Schwartz.  2012. "Chronic Exposure to Fine Particles and
       Mortality: An Extended Follow-Up of the Harvard Six Cities Study from 1974 to 2009."
       Environmental Health Perspectives, July, 120(7):965-70.


                                         4-38

-------
Marten, A. and S. Newbold. 2012. "Estimating the Social Cost of Non-CCh GHG Emissions:
       Methane and Nitrous Oxide."  Energy Policy 51:957-972.

Marten AL, Kopits KA, Griffiths CW, Newbold SC, Wolverton A. 2014. "Incremental CH4 and
       N2O mitigation benefits consistent with the US Government's SC-CO2 estimates,"
       Climate Policy 15, 2: 272-298.

Marten AL, Kopits KA, Griffiths CW, Newbold SC, Wolverton A. 2015. "Corrigendum to:
       Incremental CH4 and N2O mitigation benefits consistent with the US Government's SC-
       CO2 estimates," Climate Policy 15, 5: 678-679.

Pope, C.A., III, R.T. Burnett, MJ. Thun, E.E.  Calle, D. Krewski, K. Ito, and G.D. Thurston.
       2002. "Lung Cancer, Cardiopulmonary Mortality, and Long-term Exposure to Fine
       Parti culate Air Pollution." Journal of the American Medical Association 287:1132-1141.

Roman, H.A., K.D. Walker, T.L. Walsh, L. Conner, H.M. Richmond, J. Hubbell, and P.L.
       Kinney. 2008. "Expert Judgment Assessment of the Mortality Impact of Changes in
       Ambient Fine Particulate Matter in the U.S." Environ. Sci. Technol. 42(7):2268-2274.

Sarofim, Marcus C., S. Waldhoff, and S. Anenberg. "Valuing the Ozone-Related Health
       Benefits of Methane Emission Controls." Environmental and Resource Economics, 2015.
       DOI: 10.1007/sl0640-015-9937-6.

Shindell, D., J.C.I. Kuylenstierna, E. Vignati, R. van Dingenen, M. Amann, Z. Klimont, S.C.
       Anenberg, N. Muller, G. Janssens-Maenhout, F. Raes, J. Schwartz, G. Faluvegi, L.
       Pozzoli, K. Kupiainen, L. Hoglund-Isakson, L. Emberson, D. Streets, V. Ramanathan, K.
       Hicks, K. Oanh, G. Milly, M. Williams, V. Demkine, D. Fowler. 2012. Simultaneously
       mitigating near-term climate change and improving human health and food security,
       Science,  335:183-189.

Shindell, D.T., G. Faluvegi, N. Bell, and G.A. Schmidt. 2005. "An emissions-based view of
       climate forcing by methane and tropospheric ozone," Geophys. Res. Lett., 32, L04803,
       doi:10.1029/2004GL021900

Task Force on Hemispheric Transport of Air Pollution (HTAP). 2010. Hemispheric Transport of
       Air Pollution 2010. Informal Document No. 10. Convention on Long-range
       Transboundary Air Pollution Executive Body 28th Session.  ECE/EB.AIR/2010/10
       (Corrected). Chapter 4, pp. 148-149.

Tol, R. (2006). NEEDS Project 502687 'New Energy Externalities Developments for
       Sustainability Integrated Project' < http://www.needs-
       project.org/RSlb/NEEDS_RS!B_TP_T5.4_T5.5.pdf>. Accessed March 30, 2015.

Tol, R, R.J. Heintz, and P.E.M. Lammers. 2003. "Methane emission reduction: An application of
       FUND." Climatic Change 57(l):71-98.
                                        4-39

-------
United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) and World Meteorological Organization
      (WMO), 2011. Opportunities to Limit Near-Term Climate Change: An Integrated
      Assessment of Black Carbon and Tropospheric Ozone, and its Precursors., United
      Nations Environment Programme, Nairobi, . Accessed February
      9,2012.

United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP). 2011. Near-Term Climate Protection and
      Clean Air Benefits: Actions for Controlling Short-Lived Climate Forcers, United Nations
      Environment Programme, Nairobi.  Online at
      . Accessed March 30, 2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2006b. Regulatory Impact Analysis, 2006
      National Ambient Air Quality Standards for P articulate Matter, Chapter 5.  Office of Air
      Quality Planning and Standards, Research Triangle Park, NC.
      . Accessed
      March 30,2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 1995. Regulatory Impact Analysis for the
      Petroleum Refinery NESHAP. Revised Draft for Promulgation. Office of Air Quality
      Planning and Standards, Research Triangle Park, N.C. . Accessed March 30, 2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2009a. Integrated Science Assessment for
      Paniculate Matter (Final Report). EPA-600-R-08-139F. National Center for
      Environmental Assessment—RTF Division.
      . Accessed March 30,
      2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2009b. Technical Support Document for
      Proposed Endangerment and Cause or Contribute Findings for Greenhouse Gases under
      Section 202(a) of the Clean Air Act.
      . Accessed March 30, 2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2010a. Regulatory Impact Analysis, National
      Ambient Air Quality Standards for  Ozone. Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards,
      Research Triangle Park, NC. . Accessed March 30, 2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2010e. 40 CFR Part 98 Mandatory Reporting of
      Greenhouse Gases: Petroleum and Natural Gas Systems;  Final Rule. Federal Register
      Vol. 75, No. 229, November 30, 2010. 74458-74515.
       Accessed March 30, 2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 201 Of. Prevention of Significant Deterioration
      and Title V Greenhouse Gas Tailoring Rule. Federal Register Vol. 75, No. 106, June 3,
      2010. 31514-31608  Accessed March 30, 2015.


                                         4-40

-------
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 201 la. The Benefits and Costs of the Clean Air
      Act from 1990 to 2020. Office of Air and Radiation, Washington, DC.  March.
      . Accessed March 30, 2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 201 Ib. Regulatory Impact Analysis: National
      Emission Standards for Hazardous Air Pollutants for Industrial, Commercial, and
      Institutional Boilers and Process Heaters.  Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards,
      Research Triangle Park, NC. February.
      . Accessed
      March 30,2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 201 Ic. 2005 National-Scale Air Toxics
      Assessment. Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards, Research Triangle Park, NC.
      March. < http://www.epa.gov/ttn/atw/nata2005/> Accessed March 30,  2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 201 Id. Regulatory Impact Analysis for the
      Federal Implementation Plans to Reduce Interstate Transport of Fine P'articulate Matter
      and Ozone in 27 States; Correction of SIP Approvals for 22 States.  Office of Air Quality
      Planning and Standards, Research  Triangle Park, NC. July.
      . Accessed March 30, 2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 201 le. Draft Residual Risk Assessment for the
      Oil and Natural Gas Source Category. Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards.
      Office of Air and Radiation.

 U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2012a. Residual Risk Assessment for the Oil and
      Gas Production and Natural Gas Transmission and Storage Source Categories. Office of
      Air Quality Planning and Standards, Research Triangle Park, NC.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2012b. Regulatory Impact Analysis Final New
      Source Performance Standards and Amendments to the National Emissions Standards for
      Hazardous Air Pollutants for the Oil and Natural Gas Industry. Office of Air Quality
      Planning and Standards, Health and Environmental Impacts Division. April. <
      http ://www. epa.gov/ttn/ecas/regdata/RIAs/oil_natural_gas_fmal_neshap_nsps_ria.pdf >.
      Accessed March 30, 2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2012c. Regulatory Impact Analysis for the Final
      Revisions to the National Ambient Air Quality Standards for P articulate Matter. EPA-
      452/R-12-003. Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards, Health and Environmental
      Impacts Division. December. Available at:
      .
      Accessed March 30, 2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2012d. Regulatory Impact Analysis: Final
      Rulemakingfor 2017-2025 Light-Duty Vehicle Greenhouse Gas Emission Standards and
      Corporate Average Fuel Economy Standards.  EPA-420-R-12-016. Office of
      Transportation and Air Quality, Assessment and Standards Division. August. <
      http://www.epa.gov/otaq/climate/documents/420rl2016.pdf>.  Accessed March 30, 2015.


                                         4-41

-------
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2013. Integrated Science Assessment of Ozone
      and Related Photochemical Oxidants (Final Report). U.S. Environmental Protection
      Agency, Washington, DC, EPA/600/R-10/076F. February.
      . Accessed
      March 30,2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2014a. Health Risk and Exposure Assessment for
      Ozone (FinalReport). U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Research Triangle Park,
      NC, EPA-452/R-14-004a. August.
      . Accessed
      March 30,2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2014b. Regulatory Impact Analysis for the
      Proposed Ozone NAAQS. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Research Triangle
      Park, NC, EPA-452/P-14-006. December.
      . Accessed March 30,
      2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2015. Inventory of U.S. Greenhouse Gas
      Emissions and Sinks: 1990-2013. Office of Atmospheric Programs, Washington, DC.
      EPA 430-R-15-004. Annex 3.14, Tables A-265 and Table ES-2. April 2015.
      . Accessed
      April 28, 2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency—Science Advisory Board (EPA-SAB). 2002. Workshop
      on the Benefits of Reductions in Exposure to Hazardous Air Pollutants: Developing Best
      Estimates of Dose-Response Functions An SAB Workshop Report of an EPA/SAB
      Workshop (Final Report). EPA-SAB-EC-WKSHP-02-001. January.
      . Accessed March 30, 2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency—Science Advisory Board (EPA-SAB). 2008. Benefits of
      Reducing Benzene Emissions in Houston, 1990-2020. EPA-COUNCIL-08-001. July.
      . Accessed March 30, 2015.

Waldhoff, S., D. Anthoff, S. Rose, R.S.J. Tol. 2014. "The Marginal Damage Costs of Different
      Greenhouse Gases: An Application of FUND." The Open-Access, Open Assessment E-
      Journal. 8(31):  1-33. http://dx.doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2014-31. Accessed
      July 13, 2015.

West, J.J., A. M. Fiore, L. W. Horowitz, and D. L. Mauzerall. 2006. "Global health benefits  of
      mitigating ozone pollution with methane emission controls."  PNAS 103:11:3988-3993.

West, J.J., A.M. Fiore. 2005. "Management of tropospheric ozone by reducing methane
      emissions." Environ Sci Technol, 39:4685-4691.
                                        4-42

-------
   5   ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS AND DISTRIBUTIONAL ASSESSMENTS

5.1  Introduction

       This chapter of the RIA includes three sets of discussions related to the proposed
Emission Guidelines for MSW landfills:
   •   Economic Impact Analysis
   •   Employment Analysis
   •   Small Business Analysis
These discussions are intended to assist the reader of the RIA to better understand the potential
economic impacts of the proposal, though data and methodological limitations prevented a
complete assessment of the economic impacts of the proposed Emission Guidelines.

5.2  Economic Impact Analysis

       The impacts shown for the proposal reflect the incremental difference between facilities
in the baseline and for an option that reduces the NMOC emission rate threshold to 34 Mg/yr
from the current emissions guideline level of 50 Mg/yr (proposed option 2.5/34). The proposal
retains the design capacity threshold of 2.5 million Mg or 2.5 million cubic feet. Because the
proposed option 2.5/34 tightens the  criteria for installing and expanding the gas collection and
control system, there are incremental costs associated with capturing and/or utilizing the
additional LFG under this more stringent option. These costs were shown in Chapter 3 of this
RIA to be about $46.8 million in 2025 for the proposed option.

       Assessing the economic impacts  of these costs is difficult due to the nature of the MSW
industry. As previously discussed in Chapter 2, landfills are  owned by private companies,
government (local, state, or federal), or individuals. In 2014, 58 percent of landfills were owned
by public entities. Households served by public landfills may not respond to price increases in
the same way as they would if served by private firms, since these households typically pay their
collection fees through property taxes or other mandatory payments. In these cases, affected
landfills may be more readily able to pass through increased costs to customers. Households
served by private landfills may choose to alter their behavior in response to increased collection
fees, but research into the price elasticity of demand for waste services has typically found the
                                          5-1

-------
demand for waste services to be price inelastic (Bel and Gradus, 2014; Kinnaman, 2006). As was
shown in Table 2-5, tipping fees have for the most part increased over time, and industry reports
indicate that "firms have generally managed to hold the line on pricing and win 2-3 percent
increases to maintain positive revenue amid slow volume growth" (WBJ, 2012a). This suggests
that firms will, for the most part, be able to pass along increased costs to their consumers. While
households faced with higher costs will have less income to spend on other goods and services,
the large number of households served by any particular landfill suggests that any individual
household will be only modestly impacted.

       As previously discussed in Chapter 2, the handling of MSW in the United States
generated $55 billion of revenue in 2011, of which landfilling contributed $13 billion (WBJ,
2012a).  Of the $46.8 million  of costs in 2025 for the proposed option, 15 percent are borne by
the five largest firms in  the industry, who together accounted for nearly $30 billion in revenue in
2013 (see Table 2-3). An additional 79 percent of the costs are expected to be incurred by entities
that are  large by SBA standards. Small public entities are predicted to incur approximately six
percent  of the costs, while small private entities  are predicted to incur less than one percent of the
total cost.

       Because of the relatively low net cost of proposed option 2.5/34 compared to the overall
size of the MSW industry, as well as the lack of appropriate economic parameters or model, the
EPA is unable to estimate the impacts of the options on the supply and demand for MSW landfill
services. However, because of the relatively low incremental costs of the proposed option 2.5/34,
the EPA does not believe the proposal would lead to changes in supply and demand for landfill
services or waste disposal costs, tipping fees, or the amount of waste disposed in landfills.
Hence, the overall economic  impact of the proposal should be minimal on the affected industries
and their consumers.

5.3  Employment Impacts

       In addition to addressing the costs and benefits of the final rule, EPA has analyzed the
impacts of this rulemaking on employment, which are presented in this section. While a
standalone analysis of employment impacts is not included in a standard cost-benefit analysis,
such an analysis is of particular concern in the current economic climate given continued interest

                                          5-2

-------
in the employment impact of regulations such as this final rule.  Executive Order 13563, states,
"Our regulatory system must protect public health, welfare, safety, and our environment while
promoting economic growth, innovation, competitiveness, and job creation." 59 While
disaggregated compliance costs are not available for the analyzed options, a brief discussion of
the labor requirements associated with the installation, operation, and maintenance of control
requirements, as well as reporting and recordkeeping requirements is included in Section 3.4, on
engineering and administrative costs, of this RIA. However, due to data and methodology
limitations, we have not quantified the rule's effects on employment. What follows is an
overview of the various ways that environmental regulation can affect employment. EPA
continues to explore the relevant theoretical  and empirical literature  and to seek public comments
in order to ensure that the way EPA characterizes the employment effects of its regulations is
valid and informative.60

5.3.1  Background on the Regulated Industry

       This regulation is expected to affect domestic employment in the regulated sector -
municipal solid waste landfills. Municipal solid waste (MSW) is the stream of garbage collected
by sanitation services from homes, businesses, and institutions. The  majority of collected MSW
that is not recycled is typically  sent to landfills—engineered areas of land where waste is
deposited, compacted, and covered. Landfill gas (LFG) is a by-product of the decomposition of
organic material in MSW in anaerobic conditions in landfills. LFG contains roughly 50 percent
methane and 50 percent carbon dioxide, with less than 1 percent non-methane organic
compounds (NMOC) and trace amounts of inorganic compounds. The amount of LFG created
primarily depends on the quantity of waste and  its composition and moisture content as well as
the design and management practices at the landfill. LFG can be collected and combusted in
flares or energy recovery devices to reduce emissions. In this  rulemaking EPA is proposing to
lower the annual NMOC emissions threshold from 50 Mg/year to 34 Mg/year. Because of the
59Executive Order 13563 (January 21, 2011). Improving Regulation and Regulatory Review. Section 1. General
   Principles of Regulation, Federal Register, Vol. 76, Nr. 14, p. 3821.
60 The employment analysis in this RIA is part of EPA's ongoing effort to "conduct continuing evaluations of
   potential loss or shifts of employment which may result from the administration or enforcement of [the Act]"
   pursuant to CAA section 321 (a).

                                           5-3

-------
lack of appropriate economic parameters or model, EPA is unable to estimate the impacts of the
rule options on the supply and demand for MSW landfill services. However, because of the
relatively low incremental costs of the proposed option, the EPA does not believe the proposal
would lead to changes in supply and demand for landfill services or waste disposal costs, tipping
fees, or the amount of waste disposed in landfills. Hence, the overall economic impact of the
proposal should be minimal on the affected industries and their consumers.

       As described in Chapter 2 of this RIA, EPA estimates the total amount of MSW
generated in the United States in 2012 was approximately 251 million tons, a 20 percent increase
from 1990. The number of active MSW landfills in the United States has decreased from
approximately 7,900 in 1988 to approximately 1,800 in 2014 (EPA, 2010; WBJ, 2014). Firms
engaged in the collection and disposal of refuse in a landfill operation are classified under the
North American Industry Classification System (NAICS) codes Solid Waste Landfill (562212)
and Administration of Air and Water Resource and Solid Waste Management Programs
(924110). There are more than 200 private companies that own and/or operate landfills, ranging
from large companies with numerous landfills throughout the country to local businesses that
own a single landfill (EPA, 2012a). In terms of 2011 revenue, the top two companies that own
and/or operate MSW landfills in  the United States were Waste Management ($13.38 billion) and
Republic Services ($8.19 billion), which together accounted for 39 percent of the revenue share
in 2011 (Bloomberg, 2012WM; Bloomberg, 2012RSG). See Chapter 2, Table 2-3, for a
summary of the 2011 revenue for the top five companies, as well as information about their
MSW landfills and transfer stations.

       Landfills are owned by private companies, government (local, state, or federal), or
individuals. In 2014, 58 percent of active MSW landfills were owned by public entities while
42 percent were privately owned (EPA, 2014). As older local public landfills approach their
capacities, many communities are finding that the most economically viable solution to their
waste disposal needs is shipping  their waste to large regional landfills. In these circumstances, a
transfer station serves as the critical link in making the shipment of waste to distant facilities
cost-effective (EPA, 2002). Waste transfer stations are facilities where MSW is unloaded from
collection vehicles and reloaded into long-distance transport vehicles for delivery to regional
landfills or other treatment/disposal facilities. By combining the loads of several waste collection
                                          5-4

-------
trucks into a single shipment, communities and waste management companies can reduce labor
used and operating costs for transporting waste to a distant disposal site. They can also reduce
the total number of vehicular miles traveled to and from the disposal site(s) (EPA, 2012b).

       The industry that collects, transfers, deposits and manages MSW in landfills encompasses
a wide range of job types, including garbage collectors, truck drivers, heavy equipment
operators, engineers of various disciplines, specialized technicians, executives, MSW department
directors, administrative staff, weigh scale operators, salespersons, and landfill operations
managers. For employment estimates related to publicly-owned landfills, solid waste
management departments of local governments reported, in 2013, 95,674 full-time employees
and 14,638 part-time employees (U.S. Census Bureau, 2013); however, statistics from the U.S.
Census Bureau are not readily available solely for landfill-related aspects of these departments.
An additional government source of employment data by detailed industry is the Bureau of
Labor Statistics (BLS). The BLS Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages, which gathers
employment data from state unemployment insurance programs, reports employment data for
publicly-owned solid waste landfills (NAICS 562212) owned by local governments:  in March
2013, they report 22,586 employees (U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, 2013). For employment
estimates related to private landfills, both the U.S. Census Bureau and the Bureau of Labor
Statistics provide employment data. However, because these agencies use different methods to
gather and classify employment  data, their estimates indicate a range of employment within
NAICS 562212, "solid waste landfills".61 For March 2012, the most recent estimate from the
U.S. Census Bureau's County Business Patterns, the Census estimate is 18,208 employees at
privately-owned solid waste landfills (U.S. Census Bureau, 2012). However, for privately-owned
solid waste landfills, the BLS estimate for March 2012 is 37,628 employees (U.S. Bureau of
Labor Statistics, 2012). When data series differ, it can be instructive to look at more aggregated
industry categories, and in this case, more aggregated employment estimates are very similar
61 BLS QCEW methodology for "industrial classification": http://www.bls.gov/opub/hom/homch5_b.htm. Census
   methodology for "industry classification of establishments":
   https://www.census.gov/econ/cbp/methodology.htm.
                                          5-5

-------
between Census and BLS at the 3-digit level NAICS, 562 Waste Management and Remediation
Services. Based on observed within NAICS 562, the range in estimates at the 6-digit NAICS
562212 may be driven by methodological differences in categorizing establishments by their
"main economic activity", which for this detailed industry, is likely a combination of waste
treatment, waste disposal, and waste remediation and recovery services, and therefore difficult to
classify by a single economic activity.62

       As the population continues to grow in the United States the amount of waste generated
will continue to increase, but the amount of waste  landfilled may remain the same or decrease
due to recycling and other diversion activities (EPA, 2012c). Employment within the waste
management industry overall will likely remain strong, perhaps with an increased shift of
employees from the public sector to the private sector as the trend towards increased use of
regional landfills and waste transfer stations continues. In addition, employment may be affected
as landfills add technologies in response to the proposed regulation. Whether the technology
added will capture and flare landfill gas, or capture and combust it for energy recovery,
employment will be associated with these activities.

5.3.2   Employment Impacts of Environmental Regulation

       From an economic perspective labor is an input into producing goods and services; if a
regulation requires that more labor be used to produce a given amount of output, that additional
labor is reflected in an increase in the cost of production. Moreover, when the economy is at full
employment, we would not expect an environmental regulation to have an impact on overall
employment because labor is being shifted from one sector to another. On the other hand, in
periods of high unemployment, employment effects (both positive and negative) are possible.

       For example, an increase in labor demand due to regulation may result in a short-term net
increase in overall employment as workers are hired by the regulated sector to help meet new
requirements (e.g., to install new equipment) or by the environmental protection sector to
62 2-, 3-, 4-, 5-, and 6-digit NAICS listings for NAICS 56 "Administrative and Support and Waste Management and
   Remediation Services" < http://www.census.gov/cgi-
   bin/sssd/naics/naicsrch?chart code=56&search=2012%20NAICS%20Search>.
                                          5-6

-------
produce new abatement capital resulting in hiring previously unemployed workers . When
significant numbers of workers are unemployed, the opportunity costs associated with displacing
jobs in other sectors are likely to be smaller. And, in general, if a regulation imposes high costs
and does not increase the demand for labor, it may lead to a decrease in employment. The
responsiveness of industry labor demand depends on how these forces all interact. Economic
theory indicates that the responsiveness of industry labor demand depends  on a number of
factors: price elasticity of demand for the product, substitutability of other  factors of production,
elasticity of supply of other factors of production, and labor's share of total production costs.
Berman and Bui (2001) put this theory in the context of environmental regulation, and suggest
that, for example, if all firms in the industry are faced with the same compliance costs of
regulation and product demand is inelastic, then industry output may not change much at all.

       Regulations set in motion new orders for pollution control equipment and services. New
categories of employment have been created in the process of implementing environmental
regulations.  When a regulation is promulgated, one typical response of industry is to order
pollution control equipment and services in order to comply with the regulation when it becomes
effective. On the other hand,  the closure of plants that choose not to comply - and any changes in
production levels at plants choosing to comply and remain in operation - occur after the
compliance  date, or earlier in anticipation  of the compliance obligation. Environmental
regulation may increase revenue and employment in the environmental technology industry.
While these increases  represent gains for that industry, they translate into costs to the regulated
industries required to install the equipment.

       Environmental regulations support employment in many basic industries. Regulated firms
either hire workers to design and build pollution controls directly or purchase pollution control
devices from a third party for installation.  Once the equipment is installed, regulated firms hire
workers to operate and maintain the pollution control equipment—much like they hire workers
to produce more output. In addition to the increase in employment in the environmental
protection industry (via increased orders for pollution control equipment),  environmental
regulations also support employment in industries that provide intermediate goods to the
environmental protection industry. The equipment manufacturers, in turn, order steel, tanks,
vessels, blowers, pumps, and chemicals to manufacture and install the equipment. Currently in
                                           5-7

-------
most cases there is no scientifically defensible way to generate sufficiently reliable estimates of
the employment impacts in these intermediate goods sectors.

       It is sometimes claimed that new or more stringent environmental regulations raise
production costs thereby reducing production which in turn must lead to lower employment.
However, the peer-reviewed literature indicates that determining the direction of net employment
effects in a regulated industry is challenging due to competing effects. Environmental regulations
are assumed to raise production costs and thereby the cost of output, so we expect the "output"
effect of environmental regulation to be negative (higher prices lead to lower sales). On the other
hand, complying with the new or more stringent regulation requires additional inputs, including
labor, and may alter the relative proportions of labor and capital used by regulated firms in their
production processes. Two sets of researchers discussed here, Berman and Bui (2001) and
Morgenstern, Pizer, and Shih (2002),63 demonstrate using standard neoclassical microeconomics
that environmental regulations have an ambiguous effect on employment in the regulated sector.
These theoretical results imply that the effect of environmental regulation on employment in the
regulated sector is an empirical question and both sets of authors tested their models empirically
using different methodologies. Both Berman and Bui and Morgenstern et al. examine the effect
of environmental regulations on employment and  both find that overall they had no significant
net impact on employment in the sectors they examined.

       Berman and Bui (2001) developed an innovative approach to examine how an increase in
local air quality regulation that reduces nitrogen oxides (NOx) emissions affects manufacturing
employment in the South Coast Air Quality Management District (SCAQMD), which
incorporates Los Angeles and its suburbs. During the time frame of their study, 1979 to 1992, the
SCAQMD enacted some of the country's most stringent air quality regulations. Using
63 Berman, E. and L. T. M. Bui (2001). "Environmental Regulation and Labor Demand: Evidence from the South
   Coast Air Basin." Journal of Public Economics 79(2): 265-295. Morgenstern, R. D., W. A. Pizer, and J. S. Shih.
   2002. Jobs versus the Environment: An Industry-Level Perspective. Journal of Environmental Economics and
   Management 43(3):412-436.
                                           5-S

-------
SCAQMD's local air quality regulations, Berman and Bui identify the effect of environmental
regulations on net employment in the regulated industries.64'65 The authors find that "while
regulations do impose large costs, they have a limited effect on employment" (Berman and Bui,
2001, p. 269). Their conclusion is that local air quality regulation "probably increased labor
demand slightly" but that "the employment effects of both compliance and increased stringency
are fairly precisely estimated zeros, even when exit and dissuaded entry effects are included"
(Berman and Bui, 2001, p. 269).66

       Morgenstern et al. (2002) estimated the effects of pollution abatement expenditures from
1979 to 1991 at the plant level on net employment in four highly regulated sectors (pulp and
paper, plastics, steel, and petroleum refining). Thus, in contrast to Berman and Bui (2001), this
study identifies employment effects by examining differences in abatement expenditures rather
than geographical differences in stringency. They conclude that increased abatement
expenditures generally have not caused a significant change in net employment in those sectors.
While the specific sectors Morgenstern et al.  examined are different than  the sectors considered
here, the methodology that Morgenstern  et al. developed is still an informative way to
qualitatively, if not quantitatively, assess the  effects of this rulemaking on employment at MSW
landfills. For example,  as firms add new  technologies to capture landfill gases for flaring or for
conversion to energy, there will be a demand for labor to install, monitor, and operate these new
approaches to waste management and energy production.

       While there is an extensive empirical, peer-reviewed literature analyzing the effect of
environmental regulations on  various economic outcomes including productivity, investment,
competitiveness as well as environmental performance, there are only a few papers that examine
the impact of environmental regulation on employment, but this area of the literature has been
growing. As stated previously in this RIA section, empirical results from  Berman and Bui (2001)
and Morgenstern et al (2002)  suggest that new or more stringent environmental regulations do
64 Note, like Morgenstern, Pizer, and Shih (2002), this study does not estimate the number of jobs created in the
   environmental protection sector.
65 Berman and Bui include over 40 4-digit SIC industries in their sample.
66 Including the employment effect of exiting plants and plants dissuaded from opening will increase the estimated
   impact of regulation on employment.

                                           5-9

-------
not have a substantial impact on net employment (either negative or positive) in the regulated
sector. Similarly, Ferris, Shadbegian, and Wolverton (2014) also find that regulation-induced net
employment impacts are close to zero in the regulated sector. Furthermore, Gray et al. (2014)
find that pulp mills that had to comply with both the air and water regulations in EPA's 1998
"Cluster Rule" experienced relatively small and not always statistically significant, decreases in
employment. Nevertheless, other empirical research suggests that more highly regulated
counties may generate fewer jobs than less regulated ones (Greenstone 2002, Walker 2011).
However, the methodology used in these two studies cannot estimate whether aggregate
employment is lower or higher due to more stringent environmental regulation, it can only imply
that relative employment growth in some sectors differs between more and less regulated areas.
List et al. (2003) find some evidence that this type of geographic relocation, from more regulated
areas to less regulated areas may be occurring. Overall, the peer-reviewed literature does not
contain evidence that environmental regulation has a large impact on net employment (either
negative or positive) in the long run across the whole economy.

       While the theoretical framework laid out by Berman and Bui (2001) and Morgenstern et
al. (2002) still holds for the industries affected under these emission guidelines, important
differences in the markets and regulatory settings  analyzed in their study and the setting
presented here lead us to conclude that it is inappropriate to utilize their quantitative estimates to
estimate the employment impacts from this proposed regulation. In particular, the industries used
in these two studies as well as the timeframe (late 1970's to early 1990's) are quite different than
those in the proposed Emission Guidelines. Furthermore, the control strategies analyzed for this
RIA include gas collection systems, destruction, and utilization, which are very different than the
control strategies examined by Berman and Bui and Morgenstern et al.67 For these reasons  we
conclude there are too many uncertainties as to the transferability of the quantitative estimates in
these two studies to apply their estimates to quantify the employment impacts within the
regulated sectors for this regulation, though these  studies have usefulness for qualitative
assessment of employment impacts.
67 More detail on how emission reductions expected from compliance with this rule can be obtained can be found in
   Chapter 3 of this RIA.

                                          5-10

-------
       The preceding sections have outlined the challenges associated with estimating net
employment effects in the regulated sector and in the environmental protection sector. These
challenges make it very difficult to accurately produce net employment estimates for the whole
economy that would appropriately capture the way in which costs, compliance spending, and
environmental benefits propagate through the macro-economy. Quantitative estimates are further
complicated by the fact that macroeconomic models often have very little sectoral detail and
usually assume that the economy is at full employment. EPA's Science Advisory Board (SAB) is
currently in the process of seeking input from an independent expert panel on modeling
economy-wide impacts, including employment effects.

5.3.3   Conclusion

       Economic theory predicts  that the total effect of an environmental regulation on labor
demand in regulated sectors is not necessarily positive or negative. Peer-reviewed econometric
studies that use a structural approach, applicable to in the regulated sectors, converge on the
finding that such effects, whether positive or negative, have been small.

       Because of the lack of appropriate economic parameters or model, the EPA is unable to
estimate the impacts of the regulatory options on the supply and demand for MSW landfill
services. However, because of the relatively low incremental costs of the proposed option, the
EPA does not believe the proposal would lead to changes in supply and demand for landfill
services or waste disposal costs, tipping fees, or the amount of waste disposed in landfills.
Hence, the overall economic impact of the proposal should be minimal on the affected industries
and their consumers.

       MSW landfill activities encompasses a wide range of job types, including garbage
collectors, truck drivers,  heavy equipment operators, engineers of various disciplines, specialized
technicians, executives, MSW department directors, administrative staff, weigh scale operators,
salespersons, and landfill operations managers. As the population continues to grow in the
United States the amount of waste generated will continue to increase, but the amount of waste
landfilled may remain the same or decrease due to recycling or other waste diversion (EPA,
2012c).  Employment within the waste management industry overall will  likely remain strong,
perhaps with an increased shift of employees from the public sector to the private sector.

                                          5-11

-------
Employment to design, construct and operate new technologies for managing landfill gases
either through flaring or conversion to energy may also increase.

5.4   Small Business Impacts Analysis

       The Regulatory Flexibility Act as amended by the Small Business Regulatory
Enforcement Fairness Act (SBREFA) generally requires an agency to prepare a regulatory
flexibility analysis of any rule subject to notice and comment rulemaking requirements under the
Administrative Procedure Act or any other statute, unless the agency certifies that the rule will
not have a significant economic impact on a substantial number of small entities. Small entities
include small businesses, small governmental jurisdictions, and small not-for-profit enterprises.

       For the purposes of assessing the impact of the proposed Emission Guidelines on small
entities, a small entity is defined as: (1) A small business that is primarily engaged in the
collections and disposal of refuse in a landfill operation as defined by NAICS code 562212 with
annual receipts less than $38.5 million; (2) a small governmental jurisdiction that is a
government of a city, county, town, school district, or school district with a population of less
than 50,000; and (3) a small organization that is any not-for-profit enterprise that is
independently owned and operated and is not dominant in its field.

       After considering the economic impact of the proposed Emission Guidelines on small
entities, the EPA certifies that the proposed regulation will not have a Significant Impact on a
Substantial Number of Small Entities (SISNOSE).

       The proposed rule will not impose any requirements on small entities. Specifically,
Emission Guidelines established under CAA section 11 l(d) do not impose any requirements on
regulated entities and, thus, will not have a significant economic impact upon a substantial
number of small entities. After Emission Guidelines are promulgated, states establish standards
on existing sources and it is those state requirements that could potentially impact small entities.
Our analysis here is consistent with the analysis of the analogous situation arising when the EPA
establishes NAAQS, which do not impose any requirements on regulated entities. As here, any
impact of a NAAQS on small entities would only arise when states take subsequent action to
maintain and/or achieve the NAAQS through their state implementation plans. See American
                                          5-12

-------
Trucking Associations v. EPA, 175 F.3d 1029, 1043-45 (D.C. Cir. 1999) (NAAQS do not have

significant impacts upon small entities because NAAQS themselves impose no regulations upon

small entities).


5.5  References

Bel, Germa and Raymond Gradus. 2014. "Effects of Unit-based Pricing on the Waste Collection
       Demand: a Meta-regression Analysis." Working Paper 2014/20. Research Institute of
       Applied Economics, .

Berman, E. and L. T. M. Bui. 2001. "Environmental Regulation and Labor Demand: Evidence
       from the South Coast Air Basin." Journal of Public Economics 79(2): 265-295, docket nr.
       EPA-HQ-OAR-201 1-0135 at http://www.regulations.gov.

Bloomberg BusinessWeek. 2014RSG. 2013 SEC Filings - Republic Services Inc (RSG). 10-K,
       Annual Financials, February 13, 2014.
       
-------
Morgenstern, Richard D., William A. Pizer, and Jhih-Shyang Shih. 2002. "Jobs Versus the
      Environment: An Industry-Level Perspective." Journal of Environmental Economics and
      Management 43: 412-436, docket nr. EPA-HQOAR-2011-0135-0057 at
      http://www.regulations.gov.

U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2012. Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages. Private,
      NAICS 562212 Solid waste landfill, All States and U.S. 2012 First Quarter, All
      establishment sizes <
      http://www.bls.gov/cew/apps/table_maker/v3/table_maker.htm#type=0&year=2012&qtr
      =l&own=5&ind=562&supp=l>.

U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2013. Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages. Local
      Government, NAICS 562212 Solid waste landfill, All States and U.S. 2013 First Quarter,
      All establishment sizes <
      http://www.bls.gov/cew/apps/table_maker/v3/table_maker.htm#type=0&year=2013&qtr
      =l&own=3&ind=562212&supp=l>.

U.S. Census Bureau (Census). 2012. County Business Patterns. Solid Waste Landfill (NAICS
      562212). <
      http://factfmder. census.gov/faces/tableservices/jsf/pages/productview.xhtml?pid=BP_201
      2_OOAl&prodType=table>.

U.S. Census Bureau (Census). 2013. Annual Survey of Public Employment & Payroll. Local
      Government Employment and Payroll Data. March 2013.
      .

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2002. Solid Waste and Emergency Response.
      "Waste Transfer Stations: A Manual for Decision-Making." June 2002. EPA-530-R-02-
      002. .

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2010. "Municipal Solid Waste in the United
      States: 2009 Facts and Figures." December 2010. EPA-530-R-10-012. Washington, DC:
      U.S EPA. .
      Accessed January 6, 2015.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2012a. Office of Solid Waste and Emergency
      Response (OSWER), Office of Resource Conservation and Recovery (ORCR). Web
      page: Municipal  Solid Waste Landfills.
      . Accessed December 4, 2012.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2012b. OSWER, ORCR. Web page: MSW
      Landfill Criteria Technical Manual.
      . Accessed December 4,
      2012.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2012c. Landfill Methane Outreach Program
      (LMOP), Climate Change Division, U.S. EPA. Web page: Frequent Questions: Landfill
      Gas. . Accessed December 3, 2012.
                                        5-14

-------
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2014. "Landfill-level data only (all landfills) -
       updated August 2014." LMOP, Climate Change Division, U.S. EPA.
       .

Walker, Reed.  2011. "Environmental Regulation and Labor Reallocation." American Economic
       Review: Papers and Proceedings, 101(2).

Waste Business Journal (WBJ). 2012a. "Waste Market Overview & Outlook 2012."
       . Accessed January 16, 2015.

WBJ. 2014. "Directory of Waste Processing and Disposal Sites 2014."
       . Accessed January 6, 2015.
                                         5-15

-------
                     6    COMPARISON OF BENEFITS AND COST

6.1   Introduction

       The EPA compared the monetized methane-related climate benefits and CO2 co-benefits of
the proposed Emission Guidelines for existing landfills against the estimated annualized compliance
costs and found that the benefits of the proposed rule outweigh the costs. The net benefits are likely
larger since the EPA was not able to monetize the benefits from  reducing exposure to 2,770 Mg/yr
of NMOC. The NMOC portion of LFG can contain a variety of air pollutants, including VOC
and various organic HAP, and these pollutants are associated  with health and welfare effects
described in Chapter 4.

6.2   Net Benefits of the Proposed Standards

       For the proposed 2.5/34 option, the monetized methane-related climate benefits are
estimated to range from $310 million to $1.7 billion (2012$)68 in 2025; these benefits are
estimated to be $660 million (2012$) in 2025 using a 3% discount rate.  The CO2 co-benefits are
estimated to range from $3.6 million to $36 million (2012$)69 in 2025; estimated CO2 benefits
are $12 million (2012$) in 2025 using a 3% discount rate. Under the proposed option 2.5/34,
when using a 7% discount rate the additional cost in 2025 would be $47 million. Using a 3%
discount rate, the additional cost over the baseline in 2025 would be $35 million. Thus, the net
benefits, using a 7% discount rate, are expected to be $260 million to $1.7 billion, with a central
estimate of $620 million. These results are summarized in Table 6-1.
68 The range of estimates reflects four SC-CH4 estimates: the mean across all models and scenarios using a 2.5
   percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount rate, and the 95th percentile of the pooled estimates from all models
   and scenarios using a 3% discount rate. See Section 4.2 for a complete discussion.
69 The range of estimates reflects four SC-CCh estimates: the mean across all models and scenarios using a 2.5
   percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount rate, and the 95th percentile of the pooled estimates from all models
   and scenarios using a 3% discount rate. See Section 4.2 for a complete discussion.
                                             6-1

-------
Table 6-1  Summary of the Monetized Benefits, Costs, and Net Benefits for the Proposed
Emission Guidelines Option 2.5/34 in 2025 (2012$)

                                         3% Discount Rate            7% Discount Rate

 Monetized Methane-related Benefits1                   $310 million - $ 1.7 billion
 Monetized COa co-benefits1                           $3.6 million - $36 million
 Total Costs2                                $35 million                   $47 million
 Net Benefits                          $270 million - $ 1.7 billion      $260 million - $ 1.7 billion
 ,T       ..   , „    _. ,             Health effects of PM2 5 and ozone exposure from 2,770 Mg
 Non-monetized Benefits3             XTA*/^/    j   j
                                    NMOC/yr reduced
                                    Health effects of HAP exposure from 2,770 Mg NMOC/yr
                                    reduced
                                    Visibility impairment
                                    Vegetation effects
 1 Monetized benefits include the climate-related benefits associated with the reduction of 436,100
 Mg/yr methane, valued using the social cost of methane, and the net reduction of 238,000 Mg/yr of
 CO2, valued using the social cost of carbon. The range of estimates reflects four SC-CH4 and four SC-
 CO2 estimates: the mean across all models and scenarios using a 2.5 percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent
 discount rate, and the 95th percentile of the pooled estimates from all models and scenarios using a 3%
 discount rate. See Section 4.2 for a complete discussion.
 2 The engineering compliance costs are annualized and include estimated revenue from electricity sales
 for landfills that are expected to generate revenue by using landfill gas for energy.
 3 While we expect that these avoided emissions will result in improvements in air quality and reductions
 in health effects associated with HAP, ozone, and paniculate matter (PM), we have determined that
 quantification of those benefits cannot be accomplished for this rule in a defensible way. This is not to
 imply that these benefits do not exist; rather, it is a reflection of the difficulties in modeling the direct
 and indirect impacts of the reductions in emissions for this industrial sector with the data currently
 available.


6.3   Net Benefits of the Alternate Standards


        For the less stringent 2.5/40 option, the monetized methane-related climate benefits are

estimated to range from $190 million to $1.1 billion (2012$)™ in 2025; these benefits are

estimated to be $410 million (2012$) in 2025 using  a 3% discount rate.  The CO2 co-benefits are

estimated to range from $1.5 million to $15 million (2012$)71 in 2025; estimated  CO2 benefits

are $5.0 million (2012$) in 2025 using a 3% discount rate. Under this  option, when using a 7%
70 The range of estimates reflects four SC-CH4 estimates: the mean across all models and scenarios using a 2.5
   percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount rate, and the 95th percentile of the pooled estimates from all models
   and scenarios using a 3% discount rate. See Section 4.2 for a complete discussion.
71 The range of estimates reflects four SC-CCh estimates: the mean across all models and scenarios using a 2.5
   percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount rate, and the 95th percentile of the pooled estimates from all models
   and scenarios using a 3% discount rate. See Section 4.2 for a complete discussion.
                                                 6-2

-------
discount rate the additional cost in 2025 would be $27 million. Using a 3% discount rate, the

additional cost over the baseline in 2025 would be $20 million. Thus, the net benefits, when

using a 7% discount rate, would be expected to be $160 million to $1.1 billion, with a central

estimate of $390 million. These results are summarized in Table 6-2.


Table 6-2  Summary of the Monetized Benefits, Costs, and Net Benefits for the Alternative
Emission Guidelines Option 2.5/40 in 2025 (2012$)

                                         3% Discount Rate            7% Discount Rate

 Monetized Methane-related Benefits1                   $ 190 million -$1.1 billion
 Monetized CCh co-benefits1                           $1.5 million - $15 million
 Total Costs2                                 $20 million                   $27 million
 Net Benefits                          $ 170 million -$1.1 billion      $ 160 million -$1.1 billion
 ,T       ,.   ,„    ~^ o             Health effects of PM2 5 and ozone exposure from 1,720 Mg
 Non-monetized Benefits3             -^m^,    j   j
                                    NMOC/yr reduced
                                    Health effects of HAP exposure from 1,720 Mg NMOC/yr
                                    reduced
                                    Visibility impairment
                                    Vegetation effects
 1 Monetized benefits include the climate-related benefits associated with the reduction of 270,700
 Mg/yr methane, valued using the social cost of methane, and the net reduction of 102,000 Mg/yr of
 CO2, valued using the social cost of carbon. The range of estimates reflects four SC-CH4 and four SC-
 CO2 estimates: the mean across all models and scenarios using a 2.5 percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent
 discount rate, and the 95th percentile of the pooled estimates from all models and scenarios using a 3%
 discount rate. See Section 4.2 for a complete discussion.
 2 The engineering compliance costs are annualized and include estimated revenue from electricity  sales
 for landfills that are expected to generate revenue by using landfill gas for energy.
 3 While we expect that these avoided emissions will result in improvements in air quality and reductions
 in health effects associated with HAP, ozone, and paniculate matter (PM), we have determined that
 quantification of those benefits cannot be accomplished for this rule in a defensible way. This is not to
 imply that these benefits do not exist; rather, it is a reflection of the difficulties in modeling the direct
 and indirect impacts of the reductions in emissions for this industrial sector with the data currently
 available.

        For the more stringent 2.0/34 option, the monetized methane-related climate benefits are

estimated to range from  $340 million to $1.9 billion (2012$)72 in 2025; these benefits are
72 The range of estimates reflects four SC-CH4 estimates: the mean across all models and scenarios using a 2.5
   percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount rate, and the 95th percentile of the pooled estimates from all models
   and scenarios using a 3% discount rate. See Section 4.2 for a complete discussion.
                                                6-3

-------
estimated to be $720 million (2012$) in 2025 using a 3% discount rate.  The CO2 co-benefits are

estimated to range from $3.6 million to $36 million (2012$)73 in 2025; estimated CO2 benefits

are $12 million (2012$) in 2025 using a 3% discount rate. Under this option, when using a 7%

discount rate the additional cost in 2025 would be $51 million. Using a 3% discount rate, the

additional cost over the baseline in 2025 would be $38 million. Thus, the net benefits, when

using a 7% discount rate, would be expected to be $290 million to $1.9 billion, with a central

estimate of $690 million. These results are summarized in Table 6-3.


Table 6-3  Summary of the Monetized Benefits, Costs, and Net Benefits for the Alternative
Emission Guidelines Option 2.0/34 in 2025 (2012$)

                                        3% Discount Rate           7% Discount Rate

 Monetized Methane-related Benefits1                   $340 million - $1.9 billion
 Monetized CO2 co-benefits1                            $3.6 million - $36 million
 Total Costs2                                $38 million                   $51 million
 Net Benefits                          $300 million - $ 1.9 billion     $290 million - $ 1.9 billion
 ,T       ..   ,„   _. o             Health effects of PM2 5 and ozone exposure from 3,040 Mg
 Non-monetized Benefits              XTA*/^/    j    j
                                    NMOC/yr reduced
                                    Health effects of HAP exposure from 3,040 Mg NMOC/yr
                                    reduced
                                    Visibility impairment
                                    Vegetation effects
 1 Monetized benefits include the climate-related benefits associated with the reduction of 479,100
 Mg/yr methane, valued using the social cost of methane, and the net reduction of 238,000 Mg/yr of
 CO2, valued using the  social cost of carbon. The range of estimates reflects four SC-CH4 and four SC-
 CO2 estimates: the mean across all models and scenarios using a 2.5 percent,  3 percent, and 5 percent
 discount rate, and the 95th percentile of the pooled estimates from all models and scenarios using a 3%
 discount rate. See Section 4.2 for a complete discussion.
 2 The engineering compliance costs are annualized and include estimated revenue from electricity sales
 for landfills that are expected to generate revenue by using landfill gas for energy.
 3 While we expect that these avoided emissions will result in improvements in air quality and reductions
 in health effects associated with HAP, ozone, and paniculate matter (PM), we have determined that
 quantification of those benefits cannot be accomplished for this rule in a defensible way.  This is not to
 imply that these benefits do not exist; rather, it is a reflection of the difficulties in modeling the direct
 and indirect impacts of the reductions in emissions for this industrial sector with the data currently
 available.
73 The range of estimates reflects four SC-CCh estimates: the mean across all models and scenarios using a 2.5
   percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount rate, and the 95th percentile of the pooled estimates from all models
   and scenarios using a 3% discount rate. See Section 4.2 for a complete discussion.
                                                6-4

-------
                       7   SUPPLEMENTAL NSPS PROPOSAL

7.1  Introduction

     On July 17, 2014, the EPA proposed a new NSPS subpart resulting from its ongoing
review of the landfills NSPS (79 FR 41796). The proposed new subpart retained the same design
capacity size threshold of 2.5 million m3 or 2.5 million Mg, but presented several options for
revising the NMOC emission rate at which a MSW landfill must install controls. Since
presenting these options, the EPA has updated its model that estimates the emission reduction
and cost impacts based on public comments and  new data.

     At proposal, the EPA estimated the emission reductions and costs associated with 17 new
"greenfield" landfills that the EPA projected to commence construction, reconstruction, or
modification between 2014 and 2018 and have a design capacity of 2.5 million m3 and 2.5
million Mg.  The basis of the projected number of new landfills and associated emission
reductions is presented in the landfills NSPS docket EPA-HQ-OAR-2003-0215.  Multiple
commenters on the landfills NSPS proposal stated that the EPA underestimated the cost impacts
of the landfills NSPS because the EPA failed to consider the number of landfills that are
expected to undergo a modification, and thus become subject to the proposed NSPS. In response
to these comments, the EPA consulted with its Regional Offices, as well as state and local
authorities, to identify landfills expected to undergo a modification within the next 5 years.
Based on this information, the EPA estimated the number of existing landfills likely to modify
after July 17, 2014 and become subject to subpart XXX. In addition, the EPA has made several
changes to its underlying dataset and methodology used to analyze the impacts of potential
control options, as discussed in Chapter 3 of this RIA. Using the revised dataset, the EPA re-ran
the model and control options similar to the options presented in the proposed NSPS. As a result
of these changes, the number and characteristics  of the model new landfills and modified
landfills that are expected to become subject to proposed subpart XXX have changed. The
revised number of affected landfills, as well as revised estimates of the costs and benefits of the
previously proposed and newly proposed option, are discussed below.
                                          7-1

-------
7.2  Regulatory Baseline and Options

     The July 2014 proposed new subpart to the NSPS for MSW landfills analyzed options
slightly different from those analyzed for the current proposed revisions to the emissions
guidelines. The options analyzed in that Economic Impact Analysis were:

   •   Baseline: design capacity retained at 2.5 Mg, emission threshold retained at 50 Mg
       NMOC/year
   •   Alternative Option 3.0/40: design capacity increased to 3.0 Mg, emission threshold
       reduced to 40 NMOC Mg/yr
   •   Proposed Option 2.5/40: design capacity retained at 2.5 Mg, emission threshold reduced
       to 40 NMOC Mg/yr
   •   Alternative Option 2.0/40: design capacity reduced to 2.0 Mg, emission threshold
       reduced to 40 Mg NMOC/year.

     Consistent with the Methane Strategy that was developed as part of the President's Climate
Action Plan, when preparing this supplemental NSPS proposal the EPA considered more
stringent control options that may achieve additional reductions of methane and NMOC for new
landfills. As a result of the revised  analysis, the EPA is proposing no changes to the design
capacity threshold for new sources, but is proposing to lower the NMOC emission rate threshold
to 34 Mg/yr for new and modified sources subject to subpart XXX. In addition to responding to
feedback received during the NSPS proposal comment period, the EPA believes consistency
between the thresholds in the emission guidelines and the NSPS is important, given that an
existing landfill can modify and become subject to the proposed subpart XXX by commencing
construction on an increase in design capacity. Commenters on the July  17, 2014 notices
weighed in on consistency between the NSPS and emission guidelines. An environmental
organization recommended adopting consistent applicability  standards, such as design capacity
and NMOC emission thresholds, between subpart XXX for new landfills and subpart Cf for
existing landfills to maximize beneficial environmental impacts for existing landfills, which are
more numerous than anticipated new landfills, and to prevent creating incentives for existing
landfills subject to modification by allowing them to comply with less rigorous requirements. In
                                          7-2

-------
addition, two regulatory agencies requested harmonizing requirements for existing and new
landfills between the current regulations in subpart WWW and the new proposed subpart XXX.

       As a result, the options analyzed for this supplemental NSPS proposal for new or
modified MSW landfills match the options analyzed for the proposed revisions to the emissions
guidelines for existing MSW landfills, and are:

    •   Baseline: design capacity retained at 2.5 Mg, emission threshold retained at 50 Mg
       NMOC/year
    •   Alternative Option 2.5/40: design capacity retained at 2.5 Mg, emission threshold
       reduced to 40 NMOC Mg/yr
    •   Proposed Option 2.5/34: design capacity retained at 2.5 Mg, emission threshold reduced
       to 34 NMOC Mg/yr
    •   Alternative Option 2.0/34: design capacity reduced to 2.0 Mg, emission threshold
       reduced to 34 Mg NMOC/year

      The baseline and alternative option 2.5/40 correspond to options analyzed in the previous
NSPS proposal, and can be directly compared to the results in that economic impact analysis to
better understand the effects of the change in the number of landfills predicted to be affected by
the NSPS.74 The baseline reflects the parameters of the current NSPS. Specifically, all reported
results are incremental to the current NSPS (2.5/50) and not the proposed option (2.5/40) from
the July 2014 proposed new subpart to the NSPS for MSW landfills. In the baseline, the NSPS
affects 140 landfills, with 28 landfills reporting but not controlling emissions and 112 landfills
reporting and controlling emissions in 2025. The EPA is assessing impacts in year 2025 as a
representative year for the both the landfills Emission Guidelines and NSPS. While the analysis
focuses on impacts in 2025, results for alternative years are also presented in Section 7.8.
74 U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2014. "Economic Impact Analysis for the Proposed New
Subpart to the New Source Performance Standards." June 2014. Available at <
   http://www.epa.gov/ttn/ecas/regdata/EIAs/LandfillsNSPSProposalEIA.pdf>.
                                           7-3

-------
Table 7-1  Number of Affected Landfills in 2025 under the Baseline and Alternative
Options
                                 	Affected Landfills (no.)	
                                                        Landfills          Landfills
                                                     Reporting  but      Reporting and
                                      Landfills       Not Controlling      Controlling
                                      Affected         Emissions         Emissions
 Current NSPS = 2.5 million Mg and m3 design capacity and 50 Mg/yr NMOC	
 Baseline                               140                28                112

 Incremental values versus the current NSPS	
 Alternative option 2.5/40                  0                -11                11
 Proposed option 2.5/34                   0                -15                15
 Alternative option 2.0/34	7	-12	19	

     Based on the characteristics of the projected landfills, the proposed option presented in
Table 7-1 would require 15 additional landfills to install controls by 2025. The less stringent
alternative option 2.5/40 (which corresponds to the proposed option in the July 2014 NSPS
proposal) would require 11 additional landfills to install controls by 2025, while the more
stringent alternative option 2.0/34 would affect 22 additional landfills, with some being required
only to report and others being required to control. In that option, 19 additional landfills are
required to install controls by 2025.

     Under the proposed option 2.5/34, the emission reductions would be an additional 300 Mg
NMOC and 51,400 Mg methane (1,300,000 Mg CO2 Eq.) compared to the baseline in 2025. The
less stringent alternative option 2.5/40 would yield emissions reductions of 300 Mg NMOC and
44,400 Mg methane (1,100,000 Mg CO2 Eq.) compared to the baseline, while the more stringent
alternative option 2.0/34 would result in emissions reductions of 400 Mg NMOC and 62,500 Mg
methane  (1,600,000 Mg CO2 Eq.) compared to the baseline. The emission reductions are
summarized in Table 7-2.
                                          7-4

-------
Table 7-2  Estimated Annual Average Emissions Reductions in 2025 for the Baseline and
Alternative Options
                                        	Annual Average Reduction (Mg)	
                                                                             Methane
                                                                             (in CO2-
                                                NMOC	Methane   equivalents)*
 Current NSPS = 2.5 million Mg and m3 design capacity and 50 Mg/yr NMOC
Baseline
Incremental values versus the current NSPS
Alternative option 2.5/40
Proposed option 2.5/34
Alternative option 2.0/34
11,600
300
300
400
1,834,000
44,400
51,400
62,500
45,900,000
1,100,000
1,300,000
1,600,000
 *A global warming potential of 25 is used to convert methane to CCh-equivalents. Minor secondary air impacts
 are not included in this table. See Section 7.3 for details.
       Costs for the NSPS were estimated in the same manner as the costs for the emissions
guidelines. This methodology is discussed in Chapter 3. Under the proposed option 2.5/34, when
using a 7% discount rate the  additional cost of control in 2025 is estimated to be $9.0 million, of
which approximately $0.6 million is estimated to be offset by increased revenue from beneficial-
use projects, so the net cost is estimated to be approximately $8.5 million (Table 7-3). The cost
of control  for the less stringent alternative option 2.5/40 is estimated to be $6.6 million, which is
estimated to be supplemented by approximately $0.65 million in reduced revenue from
beneficial-use projects, so the net cost is estimated to be approximately $7.4 million. The cost of
control for the more stringent alternative option 2.0/34 is estimated to be $10.7 million, of which
approximately $0.6 million is estimated to be offset by increased revenue from beneficial-use
projects, so the net cost is estimated to be approximately $10.2 million. These options represent
approximately between 12 to 16 percent in additional net costs beyond the baseline, with the
proposed option 2.5/34 resulting in a 14 percent increase in net costs beyond the baseline for the
industry as a whole.
                                           7-5

-------
Table 7-3  Estimated Engineering Compliance Costs in 2025 for Baseline and Alternative
Options (7% Discount Rate)
Estimated Annualized Net Cost (Millions $2012)
Testing and
Monitoring
Costs
Revenue from
Beneficial-use
Control Costs Projects Net Cost
 Current NSPS = 2.5 million Mg and m3 design capacity and 50 Mg/yr NMOC
Baseline 1.3
Incremental values versus the current NSPS
Alternative option 2.5/40 0.06
Proposed option 2.5/34 0.08
Alternative option 2.0/34 0. 1 1
322

6.6
9.0
10.7
262

-0.65
0.60
0.60
61

7.4
8.5
10.2
Note: All total are independently rounded and may not sum.

     When using a 3% discount rate, the model predicts a different timing in the investment
behavior by the landfills, which affects both the costs and revenue that are predicted in 2025.
Under the proposed option 2.5/34, the additional cost of control over the baseline in 2025 is
estimated to be $12.6 million, of which $5.5 is estimated to be offset by increased revenue from
beneficial-use projects, so the net cost is  estimated to be $7.1 million (Table 7-4). The cost of
control for the less stringent alternative option 2.5/40 is estimated to be $8.0 million, of which
$1.6 million is estimated to be offset by increased revenue from beneficial-use projects, so the
net cost is estimated to be $6.4 million. The cost of control for the more stringent alternative
option 2.0/34 is estimated to be $14.9 million, of which $6.3 million is estimated to be offset by
increased revenue from beneficial-use projects, so the net cost is estimated to be $8.6 million.
These options represent approximately between 28 to 38 percent in additional net costs beyond
the baseline, with the proposed option 2.5/34 resulting in a 31 percent increase in net costs
beyond the baseline for the industry as a  whole. However, it is important to note that the baseline
value when using a 3% discount rate is less than 40 percent of the cost when using a 7% discount
rate, because the increased costs of earlier installation of GCCS and engines are offset by
increased revenue from energy generation.
                                           7-6

-------
Table 7-4  Estimated Engineering Compliance Costs in 2025 for Baseline and Alternative
Options (3% Discount Rate)
Estimated Annualized Net Cost (Millions $2012)
Testing and
Monitoring
Costs
Revenue from
Beneficial-use
Control Costs Projects Net Cost
 Current NSPS = 2.5 million Mg and m3 design capacity and 50 Mg/yr NMOC
Baseline 1.2
Incremental values versus the current NSPS
Alternative option 2.5/40 0.06
Proposed option 2.5/34 0.07
Alternative option 2.0/34 0.10
404

8
12.6
14.9
382

1.6
5.5
6.3
22

6.4
7.1
8.6
Note: All total are independently rounded and may not sum.

     In terms of cost effectiveness, when considering the estimated net cost of the options, the
overall average cost effectiveness for NMOC reductions is $5,271 per Mg NMOC under the
baseline and roughly $26,000 per Mg NMOC under the proposed option 2.5/34 and the
alternative options 2.5/40 and 2.0/34 (Table 7-5). The average cost-effectiveness of controlling
methane is significantly lower than for NMOC because methane constitutes approximately 50
percent of landfill gas, while NMOC represents less than 1 percent of landfill gas. The overall
average cost effectiveness for methane reductions is roughly $33 per Mg methane under the
baseline and approximately $160 per Mg methane under the proposed option 2.5/34 and the
alternative options 2.5/40 and 2.0/34.

     When estimating cost effectiveness excluding the estimated revenue from beneficial-use
projects, the overall average cost effectiveness for NMOC reductions is $27,800 per Mg NMOC
under the baseline and roughly $27,000 to $28,000  per Mg NMOC under the proposed option
2.5/34 and alternative option 2.0/34, and roughly $24,000 per Mg NMOC under the alternative
option 2.5/40 (Table 3-5). The average cost-effectiveness of controlling methane is significantly
lower than for NMOC because methane constitutes approximately 50 percent of landfill gas,
while NMOC represents less than 1 percent of landfill gas. The overall average cost
effectiveness for methane reductions is $176 per Mg methane under the baseline and
                                          7-7

-------
approximately $150 - $175 per Mg methane under the proposed option 2.5/34 and the alternative

options 2.5/40 and 2.0/34.

Table 7-5  Estimated Cost-effectiveness in 2025 for the Baseline and Alternative Options
(7% Discount Rate)

                             	Cost-effectiveness (2012$ per Mg)	
                                                                               Methane
                                    NMOC              Methane              (in CO2-
                             	equivalents)*
                                Net      Total      Net       Total      Net      Total
                               Costb      Cost      Costb      Cost      Costb      Cost
	/ton	/ton	/ton	/ton	/ton	/ton

         Current EG = 2.5 million Mg and m3 design capacity and 50 Mg/yr NMOC
Baseline 5,271 27,800 33.5 176
Incremental values versus the current EG
Alternative option 2.5/40 26,100 23,800 166 151
Proposed option 2. 5/34 26,100 27,900 165 177
Alternative option 2.0/34 25,600 27,100 163 172
1.3

6.6
6.6
6.5
7.1

6.0
7.1
6.9
Note: The cost-effectiveness of NMOC and methane are estimated as if all of the control cost were attributed to each
pollutant separately.
a A global warming potential of 25 is used to convert methane to CO2-equivalents. The secondary COa emission
reductions are not reflected in these estimates.
b Net Cost is the total control and testing and monitoring cost minus any project revenue. The control costs for
landfills with energy projects includes costs to install and operate a reciprocating engine (and associated electrical
equipment), which is more expensive than a standard flare. Reciprocating engines are not required by the regulation
but are expected to be used as control devices when it is cost-effective to recovery the LFG energy.
7.3   Benefits

       The proposed subpart to the NSPS is expected to result in significant emissions

reductions of landfill gas (LFG) from new or modified MSW landfills. By lowering the current

NMOC emissions threshold of 50 Mg/yr to 34 Mg/yr, the proposal is anticipated to achieve

reductions of 300 Mg/yr NMOC and 51,400 Mg/yr methane in 2025. The NMOC portion of

LFG can contain a variety of air pollutants, including VOC and various organic HAP. VOC

emissions are precursors to both fine particulate matter (PM2.s) and ozone formation, while

methane is a GHG and a precursor to global ozone formation. As described in detail in Chapter

4, these pollutants are associated with substantial health effects, climate effects, and other

                                             7-8

-------
welfare effects. As with the proposed emissions guidelines, the only categories of benefits
monetized for the proposed NSPS are methane-related and CCh-related climate effects. While
the methane-related climate effects are positive as with the proposed emissions guidelines, for
the proposed NSPS there are small CO2 disbenefits associated with increased electricity demand
due to the energy demands of the GCCS exceeding the increased generation of electricity by
landfills through the burning of LFG in engines.

      While we expect that these avoided emissions will also result in improvements in air
quality and reduce health and welfare effects associated with exposure to HAP, ozone, and fine
paniculate matter (PIVh.s), we have determined that quantification of those health benefits cannot
be accomplished for this rule in a defensible way. This is not to imply that these benefits do not
exist; rather, it is a reflection of the difficulties in modeling the direct and indirect impacts of the
reductions in emissions for this industrial sector with the data currently available.

      The methodology used to calculate methane climate benefits is discussed in detail in
Section 4.2 of this RIA. Applying the approach discussed in that section to the CH4 reductions
estimated for this proposal, the 2025 methane benefits vary by discount rate and range from
about $36 million to approximately $210 million; for the proposed option, the mean SC-CH4 at
the 3% discount rate results in an estimate of about $78 million in 2025. These benefits are
presented below in Table 7-6.
                                           7-9

-------
Table 7-6 Estimated Global Benefits of CH4 Reductions in 2025* (in millions, 2012$)





Alternative Option 2.5/40
Proposed Option 2.5/34
Alternative Option 2.0/34
Million
metric

tonnes of
CH4
reduced

0.044
0.051
0.063
Million
metric
tonnes of
CO2-
equivalent
reduced
1.1
1.3
1.6
Discount rate and statistic

5%
(average)

$32
$36
$44

3%
(average)

$67
$78
$95

2.5%
(average)

$86
$100
$120

3% (95th
percentile)

$180
$210
$250
 *The SC-CH4 values are dollar-year and emissions-year specific. SC-CH4 values represent only a partial
 accounting of climate impacts.
      However, there are climate-related disbenefits that are expected from the proposal's

secondary air impacts, specifically, a net increase in CO2 emissions. These disbenefits arise

because more energy is required to operate the GCCS at some landfills than is produced by these

landfills through the burning of LFG in engines.75 These disbenefits are presented in Table 7-7

below.  Monetizing the net CO2 increases with the SC-CCh estimates also described in Section

4.2 yields disbenefits that vary by discount rate and range from about $0.01 million to

approximately $0.10 million in 2025. For the proposed option, the mean SC-CO2 at the 3%

discount rate results in an estimate of about $0.03 million in 2025.


Table 7-7 Estimated Global Disbenefits of Net COi Increases in 2025* (in millions, 2012$)

                           , „ , .  ,        ,               Discount rate and statistic
                           Metric tonnes ot net
                              C02 increased         5%         3%        2'5%      3%(95*
                                                  (average)    (average)    (average)   percentile)
Alternative Option 2.5/40
Proposed Option 2.5/34
Alternative Option 2.0/34
11,000
670
2,000
$0.17
$0.010
$0.030
$0.55
$0.033
$0.10
$0.81
$0.049
$0.14
$1.6
$0.10
$0.29
 *The SC-CCh values are dollar-year and emissions-year specific. SC-CCh values represent only a partial
 accounting of climate impacts.
 ' As in the case of the proposed Emissions Guidelines, there is an additional CCh impact, specifically a small
   increase in CCh emissions resulting from flaring of methane in response to this rule. We are not estimating the
   monetized disbenefits of these secondary emissions of CCh because much of the methane that would have been
   released in the absence of the flare would have eventually oxidized into CCh in the atmosphere. See Section 4.2.1
   for more discussion.
                                             7-10

-------
7.4  Economic Impacts

7.4.1   Economic Impact A nalysis

       As was discussed in Section 5.2, assessing the economic impacts of the costs of the
proposed option is difficult due to the nature of the MSW industry. The cost of the current
proposal is estimated to be $8.5 million in 2025. Because of the relatively low net cost of
proposed option 2.5/34 compared to the overall size of the MSW industry as was discussed in
Chapter 2 and Section 5.2, as well as the lack of appropriate economic parameters or model, the
EPA is unable to estimate the impacts of the options on the supply and demand for MSW landfill
services. However, because of the relatively low incremental  costs of the proposed option 2.5/34,
the EPA does not believe the proposal would lead to changes in supply and demand for landfill
services or waste disposal costs, tipping fees, or the amount of waste disposed in landfills.
Hence, the overall economic impact of the proposal should be minimal on the affected industries
and their  consumers.

7.4.2   Employment Impacts

     As  is the case with the proposed emissions guidelines, the EPA is unable to quantify the
effect of the proposed NSPS on employment. However, a discussion of the potential impacts on
employment appears in  Section 5.3, and is relevant for the proposed NSPS as well  as the
proposed emissions guidelines.

7.4.3   Small Business Impacts Analysis

     As  discussed in Section 5.4, the Regulatory Flexibility Act as amended by the Small
Business  Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act (SBREFA) generally requires an agency to
prepare a regulatory flexibility analysis of any rule subject to notice and  comment rulemaking
requirements under the Administrative Procedure Act or any other statute, unless the agency
certifies that the rule will not have a significant economic impact on a substantial number of
small entities. Small entities include small businesses, small governmental jurisdictions, and
small not-for-profit enterprises.
                                         7-11

-------
     It was determined that the July 2014 proposed NSPS subpart would not have a significant
economic impact on a substantial number of small entities. Given the changes in the number of
landfills anticipated to become subject to the new proposed NSPS, the potential impact on small
entities has been reanalyzed.

       For the purposes of assessing the impact of the proposed NSPS on small entities, a small
entity is defined as: (1) A small business that is primarily engaged in the collections and disposal
of refuse in a landfill operation as defined by NAICS code 562212 with annual receipts less than
$38.5 million; (2) a small governmental jurisdiction that is a government of a city, county, town,
school district, or school district with a population of less than 50,000;  and  (3) a small
organization that is any not-for-profit enterprise that is independently owned and operated and is
not dominant in its field.

       The EPA typically assessed how the regulatory program may potentially impact owners
(ultimate parent companies, governmental jurisdictions, or not-for-profit enterprises) by
comparing pollution control costs to total sales or revenue. This is referred to as a "sales" test or
cost-to-sales ratio. To perform this test,  the total annualized control cost for a small entity (/') is
divided by its reported revenue:

                                 Total Annualized Compliance
                   Sales Testi =
                                            Total Revenuei

       The "sales test" is the impact metric the EPA employs in analyzing small entity impacts
as opposed to a "profits test," in which annualized compliance costs are calculated as a share of
profits.  The use of a "sales test" for estimating small business impacts for a rulemaking such as
this one is consistent with guidance offered by the EPA on compliance with SBREFA76 and is
consistent with guidance published by the U.S.  SBA's Office of Advocacy that suggests that cost
76 The SBREFA compliance guidance to EPA rulewriters regarding the types of small business analysis that should
   be considered can be found at 
                                          7-12

-------
as a percentage of total revenues is a metric for evaluating cost increases on small entities in
relation to increases on large entities.77 The results of the screening analysis appear below in
Table 7-8.

Table 7-8  Small Business Impact Screening Assessment Results (Reporters and
Controllers)







No. Affected
No. Affected with Sales Data
No. Affected > 1% (n)
No. Affected > 3% (n)
No. Affected > 1% (%)
No. Affected > 3% (%)
2.5 million Mg;
Reduce to 40 Mg/yr
NMOC
Count from Count from
Screen Screen
Based on Based on
Total Cost Net Cost
13 13
11 11
0 0
0 0
0.0% 0.0%
0.0% 0.0%
2.5 million Mg;
Reduce to 34 Mg/yr
NMOC
Count from Count from
Screen Screen
Based on Based on
Total Cost Net Cost
13 13
11 11
2 2
1 1
18.2% 18.2%
9.1% 9.1%
2.0 million Mg;
Reduce to 34 Mg/yr
NMOC
Count from Count from
Screen Screen
Based on Based on
Total Cost Net Cost
14 14
12 12
2 2
1 1
16.7% 16.7%
8.3% 8.3%
     After considering the economic impact of the proposed NSPS on small entities, the
analysis indicates that this rule will not have a significant impact on a substantial number of
small entities (SISNOSE). First, the proposed revision does not impact a substantial number of
small entities, since only 13 small entities are projected to be impacted by the proposed option.
Additionally, the impact to these entities are not significant, because only 2 entities have impacts
greater than 1 percent of sales, and only 1 of these 2 entities has impacts greater than 3 percent of
sales.

7.5  Comparison of Benefits and Costs

       The EPA compared the monetized methane-related climate benefits and CO2 co-benefits
of the proposed NSPS for new or modified MSW landfills against the estimated annualized costs
77U.S. SB A, Office of Advocacy. A Guide for Government Agencies, How to Comply with the Regulatory
   Flexibility Act, Implementing the President's Small Business Agenda and Executive Order 13272, June 2010.
                                          7-13

-------
and found that the benefits of the proposed rule outweigh the costs. The net benefits are likely
larger since the EPA was not able to monetize the benefits from reducing exposure to 300 Mg/yr
of NMOC. The NMOC portion of LFG can contain a variety of air pollutants, including VOC
and various organic HAP, and these pollutants are associated with health and welfare effects
described in Chapter 4.

7.6   Net Benefits of the Proposed Standards

       For the proposed 2.5/34 option, the monetized methane-related climate benefits are
estimated to range from $36 million to $210 million (2012$)78 in 2025; these benefits are
estimated to be $78 million (2012$) in 2025 using a 3% discount rate.  The CO2 disbenefits are
estimated to range from $0.01 million to $0.10 million (2012$)79 in 2025; estimated CO2
disbenefits are $0.033 million (2012$) in 2025 using a 3% discount rate. Under the proposed
option 2.5/34, when using a 7% discount rate the additional cost in 2025 would be $8.5 million.
Using a 3% discount rate, the additional cost over the baseline in 2025 would be $7.1 million.
Thus, the net benefits in 2025, when using a 7% discount rate, are expected to be $28 million to
$200 million, with a central estimate of $69 million. These results are summarized in Table 7-9.
78 The range of estimates reflects four SC-CH4 estimates: the mean across all models and scenarios using a 2.5
   percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount rate, and the 95th percentile of the pooled estimates from all models
   and scenarios using a 3% discount rate. See Section 4.2 for a complete discussion.
79 The range of estimates reflects four SC-CCh estimates: the mean across all models and scenarios using a 2.5
   percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount rate, and the 95th percentile of the pooled estimates from all models
   and scenarios using a 3% discount rate. See Section 4.2 for a complete discussion.
                                            7-14

-------
Table 7-9  Summary of the Monetized Benefits, Costs, and Net Benefits for the Proposed
NSPS Option 2.5/34 in 2025 (2012$)

                                         3% Discount Rate            7% Discount Rate

 Monetized Methane-related Benefits1                   $36 million - $210 million
 Monetized CO2 disbenefits1                         $0.010 million -$0.10 million
 Total Costs2                                $7.1 million                  $8.5 million
 Net Benefits                          $29 million - $200 million      $28 million - $200 million
 , T       ..   , „    -.. -,             Health effects of PM2 5 and ozone exposure from 300 Mg
 Non-monetized Benefits3             XTA*/^/    j    j
                                    NMOC/yr reduced
                                    Health effects of HAP exposure from 300 Mg NMOC/yr
                                    reduced
                                    Visibility impairment
                                    Vegetation effects
 1 Monetized benefits include the climate-related benefits associated with the reduction of 51,400 Mg/yr
 methane, valued using the social cost of methane, and the net increase of 665 Mg/yr of CCh, valued
 using the social cost of carbon. The range of estimates reflects four SC-CH4 and four SC-CCh
 estimates: the mean across all models and scenarios using a 2.5 percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent
 discount rate, and the 95th percentile of the pooled estimates from all models and scenarios using a 3%
 discount rate. See Section 4.2 for a complete discussion.
 2 The engineering compliance costs are annualized and include estimated revenue from electricity  sales
 for landfills that are expected to generate revenue by using landfill gas for energy.
 3 While we expect that these avoided emissions will result in improvements in air quality and reductions
 in health effects associated with HAP, ozone, and paniculate matter (PM),  we have determined that
 quantification of those benefits cannot be accomplished for this rule in a defensible way. This is not to
 imply that these benefits do not exist; rather, it is a reflection of the difficulties in modeling the direct
 and indirect impacts of the reductions in emissions for this industrial sector with the data currently
 available.


7.7   Net Benefits of the Alternate Standards


        For the less stringent 2.5/40 option, the monetized methane-related climate  benefits are

estimated to range from $31 million to $180 million (2012$)80 in 2025; these benefits are

estimated to be $67 million (2012$) in 2025 using a 3% discount rate. The CO2 disbenefits are

estimated to range from $0.17 million to  $1.6 million (2012$)81 in 2025; estimated  CO2

disbenefits are $0.55 million (2012$) in 2025 using a  3% discount rate. Under this  option,  when
80 The range of estimates reflects four SC-CH4 estimates: the mean across all models and scenarios using a 2.5
   percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount rate, and the 95th percentile of the pooled estimates from all models
   and scenarios using a 3% discount rate. See Section 4.2 for a complete discussion.
81 The range of estimates reflects four SC-CCh estimates: the mean across all models and scenarios using a 2.5
   percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount rate, and the 95th percentile of the pooled estimates from all models
   and scenarios using a 3% discount rate. See Section 4.2 for a complete discussion.
                                                7-15

-------
using a 7% discount rate the additional cost in 2025 would be $7.4 million. Using a 3% discount
rate, the additional cost over the baseline in 2025 would be $6.4 million. Thus, the net benefits,
when using a 7% discount rate, would be expected to be $23 million to $170 million in 2025,
with a primary estimate of $59 million. These results are summarized in Table 7-10.
                                          7-16

-------
Table 7-10  Summary of the Monetized Benefits, Costs, and Net Benefits for the
Alternative NSPS Option 2.5/40 in 2025 (2012$)

                                         3% Discount Rate            7% Discount Rate

 Monetized Methane-related Benefits1                   $31 million - $ 180 million
 Monetized CO2 disbenefits1                          $0.17 million - $ 1.60 million
 Total Costs2                                $6.4 million                  $7.4 million
 Net Benefits                          $24 million - $ 170 million      $23 million - $ 170 million
 , T       ..   , „    -.. -,             Health effects of PM2 5 and ozone exposure from 300 Mg
 Non-monetized Benefits3             XTA*/^/    j    j
                                    NMOC/yr reduced
                                    Health effects of HAP exposure from 300 Mg NMOC/yr
                                    reduced
                                    Visibility impairment
                                    Vegetation effects
 1 Monetized benefits include the climate-related benefits associated with the reduction of 44,400 Mg/yr
 methane, valued using the social cost of methane, and the net increase of 11,000 Mg/yr of CCh, valued
 using the social cost of carbon. The range of estimates reflects four SC-CH4 and four SC-CCh
 estimates: the mean across all models and scenarios using a 2.5 percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent
 discount rate, and the 95th percentile of the pooled estimates from all models and scenarios using a 3%
 discount rate. See Section 4.2 for a complete discussion.
 2 The engineering compliance costs are annualized and include estimated revenue from electricity sales
 for landfills that are expected to generate revenue by using landfill gas for energy.
 3 While we expect that these avoided emissions will result in improvements in air quality and reductions
 in health effects associated with HAP, ozone, and paniculate matter (PM), we have determined that
 quantification of those benefits cannot be accomplished for this rule in a defensible way. This is not to
 imply that these benefits do not exist; rather, it is a reflection of the difficulties in modeling the direct
 and indirect impacts of the reductions in emissions for this industrial sector with the data currently
 available.

        For the more stringent 2.0/34 option, the monetized methane-related climate benefits are

estimated to range from $44 million to $250 million (2012$)82 in 2025; these benefits are

estimated to be $95 million (2012$) in 2025 using a 3% discount rate.  The CO2 disbenefits are

estimated to range from $0.03 million to  $0.29 million (2012$)83 in 2025; estimated CO2

disbenefits are $0.10 million (2012$) in 2025 using a  3% discount rate. Under this option, when

using a 7% discount rate the additional cost in 2025 would be $10 million. Using a 3% discount

rate, the additional cost over the baseline in 2025 would be  $8.6 million. Thus, the net benefits,
82 The range of estimates reflects four SC-CH4 estimates: the mean across all models and scenarios using a 2.5
   percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount rate, and the 95th percentile of the pooled estimates from all models
   and scenarios using a 3% discount rate. See Section 4.2 for a complete discussion.
83 The range of estimates reflects four SC-CCh estimates: the mean across all models and scenarios using a 2.5
   percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount rate, and the 95th percentile of the pooled estimates from all models
   and scenarios using a 3% discount rate. See Section 4.2 for a complete discussion.
                                                7-17

-------
when using a 7% discount rate, would be expected to be $34 million to $240 million in 2025,

with a primary estimate of $85 million. These results are summarized in Table 7-11.


Table 7-11  Summary of the Monetized Benefits, Costs, and Net Benefits for the
Alternative NSPS Option 2.0/34 in 2025 (2012$)

                                       3% Discount Rate            7% Discount Rate
 Monetized Methane-related Benefits1                  $44 million - $250 million
 Monetized CO2 disbenefits1                         $0.03 million - $0.29 million
 Total Costs2                               $8.6 million                $10.0 million
 Net Benefits                         $35 million - $240 million      $34 million - $240 million
 , T       ,.  , „   ~^ ,             Health effects of PM2 5 and ozone exposure from 400 Me
 Non-monetized Benefits             -^m^,    j   j
                                   NMOC/yr reduced
                                   Health effects of HAP exposure from 400 Mg NMOC/yr
                                   reduced
                                   Visibility impairment
                                   Vegetation effects
 1 Monetized benefits include the climate-related benefits associated with the reduction of 62,500 Mg/yr
 methane, valued using the social cost of methane, and the net increase of 1,970 Mg/yr of CCh, valued
 using the social cost of carbon.  The range of estimates reflects four SC-CH4 and four SC-CCh
 estimates: the mean across all models and scenarios using a 2.5 percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent
 discount rate, and the 95th percentile of the pooled estimates from all models and scenarios using a 3%
 discount rate. See Section 4.2 for a complete discussion.
 2 The engineering compliance costs are annualized and include estimated revenue from electricity sales
 for landfills that are expected to generate revenue by  using landfill gas for energy.
 3 While we expect that these avoided emissions will result in improvements in air quality and reductions
 in health effects associated with HAP, ozone, and paniculate matter (PM),  we have determined that
 quantification of those benefits cannot be accomplished for this rule in a defensible way. This is not to
 imply that these benefits do not exist; rather, it is a reflection of the difficulties in modeling the direct
 and indirect impacts of the reductions in emissions for this industrial sector with the data currently
 available.


7.8     Alternative Years of Analysis


        While  the EPA is assessing impacts in year 2025 as  a representative year for the landfills

NSPS for new or modified  MSW landfills, the quantity and composition of landfill gas does

change over the lifetime of a landfill, as discussed in Chapter 2. This section presents a more

complete picture  of the emission reductions, costs, and benefits of the NSPS alternatives over

time by presenting results from the years 2020,  2030, and 2040. Throughout this section, costs

are presented only at a 7% interest rate, and do not include testing and monitoring costs.

However,  testing and monitoring costs are typically a very small percentage of the overall costs.

Tables 7-12  and 7-13 present the emissions reductions and compliance costs, respectively, of the

alternatives in the 2020 snapshot year.
                                              7-18

-------
Table 7-12  Estimated Annual Average Emissions Reductions in 2020 for the Baseline and
Alternative Options

                                     	Annual Average Reduction (Mg)	
                                                                            Million
                                                                            Methane
                                                              Million       (in CO2-
                                             NMOC	Methane     equivalents)*
 Current NSPS = 2.5 million Mg and m3 design capacity and 50 Mg/yr NMOC	
 Baseline                                    10,100             1.6           39.9

 Incremental values versus the current NSPS	
 Alternative option 2.5/40                       400              0.06           1.6
 Proposed option 2.5/34                        470              0.07           1.9
 Alternative option 2.0/34	550	0.09	2.2
 *A global warming potential of 25 is used to convert methane to CCh-equivalents. Secondary CCh emission
 reductions are not included in this table.
Table 7-13  Estimated Engineering Compliance Costs in 2020 for Baseline and Alternative
Options (7% Discount Rate)
                                             Estimated Annualized Net Cost (Millions
                                                              2012$)
Landfills
Controlling
Emissions
Control Costs
Revenue from
Beneficial-use
Projects
Net Cost
 Current NSPS = 2.5 million Mg and m3 design capacity and 50 Mg/yr NMOC	
 Baseline                        106            294            251            42.0

 Incremental values versus the current NSPS
 Alternative option 2.5/40           13             13.2             6.5             6.7
 Proposed option 2.5/34            16             15.9             8.3             7.6
 Alternative option 2.0/34	20	17.5	83	9.3
Note: All total are independently rounded and may not sum. Costs do not include testing and monitoring costs.

Tables 7-14 and 7-15 present the emissions reductions and compliance costs, respectively, in the
2030 snapshot year.
                                          7-19

-------
Table 7-14  Estimated Annual Average Emissions Reductions in 2030 for the Baseline and
Alternative Options
                                     	Annual Average Reduction (Mg)	
                                                                            Million
                                                                            Methane
                                                              Million       (in CO2-
                                            NMOC	Methane     equivalents)*
 Current NSPS = 2.5 million Mg and m3 design capacity and 50 Mg/yr NMOC	
 Baseline                                    12,200              1.9           48.1

 Incremental values versus the current NSPS	
 Alternative option 2.5/40                      190              0.03           0.7
 Proposed option 2.5/34                        270              0.04           1.1
 Alternative option 2.0/34	330	0.05	L3_
 *A global warming potential of 25 is used to convert methane to CCh-equivalents. Secondary CCh emission
 reductions are not included in this table.
Table 7-15  Estimated Engineering Compliance Costs in 2030 for Baseline and Alternative
Options (7% Discount Rate)
                                             Estimated Annualized Net Cost (Millions
                                                              2012$)
Landfills
Controlling
Emissions
Control Costs
Revenue from
Beneficial-use
Projects
Net Cost
 Current EG = 2.5 million Mg and m3 design capacity and 50 Mg/yr NMOC	
 Baseline                        115            331             258           74.0

                        Incremental values versus the current EG
 Alternative option 2.5/40          7             3.8             -0.5            4.3
 Proposed option 2.5/34            12            5.9             -1.0            7.0
 Alternative option 2.0/34	16	7^6	-LO	8.6
Note: All total are independently rounded and may not sum. Costs do not include testing and monitoring costs.
                                          7-20

-------
Tables 7-16 and 7-17 present the emissions reductions and compliance costs, respectively, in the
2040 snapshot year.

Table 7-16  Estimated Annual Average Emissions Reductions in 2040 for the Baseline and
Alternative Options

                                     	Annual Average Reduction (Mg)	
                                                                             Million
                                                                            Methane
                                                              Million       (in CO2-
                                            NMOC	Methane     equivalents)*
 Current EG = 2.5 million Mg and m3 design capacity and 50 Mg/yr NMOC	
 Baseline                                    11,600             1.8           45.7

 Incremental values versus the current EG	
 Alternative option 2.5/40                      220               0.03            0.9
 Proposed option 2.5/34                        350               0.05            1.4
 Alternative option 2.0/34	360	0.06	1.4
 *A global warming potential of 25 is used to convert methane to CCh-equivalents. Secondary CCh emission
 reductions are not included in this table.
Table 7-17  Estimated Engineering Compliance Costs in 2040 for Baseline and Alternative
Options (7% Discount Rate)
                                              Estimated Annualized Net Cost (Millions
                                           	2012$)	
                               Landfills                    Revenue from
                              Controlling                   Beneficial-use
                              Emissions    Control Costs	Projects	Net Cost
Current
Baseline
EG = 2
.5
million
Mg and m3 design
capacity and
50 Mg/yr
NMOC
107 321 228
Incremental values versus the current EG
Alternative option
Proposed option 2.
Alternative option
2.5/40
5/34
2.0/34
7
12
13
5.0
11.6
12.0
-0
3.
3.
.4
2
2

93
5.
8.
8.

.0
3
4
7
Note: All total are independently rounded and may not sum. Costs do not include testing and monitoring costs.

Table 7-18 presents the climate benefits of the alternatives in the 2020 snapshot year.
                                          7-21

-------
Table 7-18 Estimated Global Benefits of CH4 Reductions in 2020* (in millions, 2012$)





Alternative Option 2.5/40
Proposed Option 2.5/34
Alternative Option 2.0/34
Million
metric

tonnes of
CH4
reduced

0.063
0.074
0.087
Million
metric
tonnes of
CO2-
equivalent
reduced
1.6
1.9
2.2
Discount rate and statistic

5%
(average)

$37
$43
$51

3%
(average)

$82
$96
$110

2.5%
(average)

$110
$130
$150

3% (95th
percentile)

$220
$260
$300
 *The SC-CH4 values are dollar-year and emissions-year specific. SC-CH4 values represent only a partial
 accounting of climate impacts.

Table 7-19 presents the climate benefits of the alternatives in the 2030 snapshot year.


Table 7-19 Estimated Global Benefits of CH4 Reductions in 2030* (in millions, 2012$)





Alternative Option 2.5/40
Proposed Option 2.5/34
Alternative Option 2.0/34
Million
metric

tonnes of
CH4
reduced

0.029
0.042
0.052
Million
metric
tonnes of
CO2-
equivalent
reduced
0.73
1.1
1.3
Discount rate and statistic

5%
(average)

$24
$35
$42

3%
(average)

$50
$73
$89

2.5%
(average)

$63
$92
$110

3% (95th
percentile)

$130
$190
$230
 *The SC-CH4 values are dollar-year and emissions-year specific. SC-CH4 values represent only a partial
 accounting of climate impacts.


Table 7-20 presents the climate benefits of the alternatives in the 2040 snapshot year.
Table 7-20 Estimated Global Benefits of CH4 Reductions in 2040* (in millions, 2012$)





Alternative Option 2.5/40
Proposed Option 2.5/34
Alternative Option 2.0/34
Million
metric

tonnes of
CH4
reduced

0.035
0.055
0.056
Million
metric
tonnes of
CO2-
equivalent
reduced
0.87
1.4
1.4
Discount rate and statistic

5%
(average)

$38
$59
$61

3%
(average)

$75
$120
$120

2.5%
(average)

$98
$150
$160

3% (95th
percentile)

$210
$330
$330
 *The SC-CH4 values are dollar-year and emissions-year specific. SC-CH4 values represent only a partial
 accounting of climate impacts.
                                            7-22

-------
               8   STATUTORY AND EXECUTIVE ORDER REVIEWS

8.1  Executive Order 12866, Regulatory Planning and Review and Executive Order
     13563, Improving Regulation and Regulatory Review

       Under section 3(f)(l) of Executive Order (EO) 12866 (58 FR 51735, October 4, 1993),
this action is an "economically significant regulatory action" because it is likely to have an
annual effect on the economy of $100 million or more. Accordingly, the EPA submitted this
action to the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) for review under EO 12866  and 13563
(76 FR 3821, January 21, 2011) and any changes made in response to OMB recommendations
have been documented in the docket for this action. In addition, the EPA prepared this RIA of
the potential costs and benefits associated with this action. For the proposed Emission
Guidelines, the monetized methane-related climate benefits are estimated to range from $310
million to $1.7 billion (2012$); these benefits are estimated to be $660  million (2012$) in 2025
using a 3% discount rate.  The CO2 co-benefits  are estimated to range from $3.6 million to $36
million (2012$) in 2025; estimated CO2 benefits are $12 million (2012$) in 2025 using a 3%
discount rate. Under the proposed option 2.5/34, when using a 3% discount rate, the  additional
cost over the baseline in 2025 would be $47 million. When using a 7% discount rate, the
additional cost in 2025 would be $35 million. Thus, the net benefits are expected to be $260
million to $1.7 billion, with a primary estimate  of $620 million. Table 6-1  shows the results of
the cost and benefits analysis for this proposed rule.

       The EPA also considered the impacts associated with the proposed revision to the NSPS
and has concluded that the proposed NSPS is also economically significant. For the proposed
rule, the monetized methane-related climate benefits are estimated to range from $36 million to
$210 million (2012$) in 2025, depending on the discount rate; these benefits are estimated to be
$78 million (2012$) in 2025 using a 3% discount rate. The CO2 disbenefits are estimated to
range from $0.01 million to $0.10 million (2012$) in 2025, depending on the discount rate;
estimated CO2 disbenefits are $0.033 million (2012$) in 2025 using a 3% discount rate. Under
the proposed option 2.5/34, when using a 7% discount rate the additional cost in 2025 would be
$8.5 million. Using a 3% discount rate, the additional cost over the baseline in 2025  would be
                                          8-1

-------
$7.1 million. Thus, the net benefits in 2025 are expected to be $28 million to $200 million, with
a central estimate of $69 million. These results are summarized in Table 7-9.

8.2  Paperwork Reduction Act

       The information collection requirements in the proposed Emission Guidelines have been
submitted for approval to OMB under the PRA. The Information Collection Request (ICR)
document that the EPA prepared for the proposed Emission Guidelines has been assigned EPA
ICR number [2522.01]. You can find a copy of the ICR in the docket for this rule, and it is
briefly summarized here.

       The information required to be collected is necessary to identify the regulated entities
subject to the proposed rule and to ensure their compliance with the proposed Emission
Guidelines. The recordkeeping and reporting requirements are mandatory and are being
established under authority of CAA section 114 (42 U.S.C. 7414). All  information other than
emissions data submitted as part of a report to the agency for which a claim of confidentiality is
made will be safeguarded according to CAA section 114(c) and the EPA's implementing
regulations at 40 CFR part 2, subpart B.

       Respondents/affected entities: Municipal solid waste landfills that accepted waste on or
       after November 8, 1987 and commenced construction, reconstruction, or modification on
       or before July 17,2014.

       Respondent's obligation to respond: Mandatory (40 CFR part 60, subpart Cf).

       Estimated number of respondents: 988 municipal solid waste landfills.

       Frequency of response: Initially, occasionally and annually.

       Total estimated burden: 621,947 hours (per year) for the responding facilities and 16,054
       hours (per year) for the agency. These are estimates for the average annual burden for the
       first 3 years after the rule is final. Burden is defined at 5 CFR 1320.3(b).
                                          8-2

-------
       Total estimated cost: $41,755,793 (per year), which includes annualized capital or
       operation and maintenance costs, for the responding facilities and $1,029,658 (per year)
       for the agency. These are estimates for the average annual cost for the first 3 years after
       the rule is final.

       The information collection requirements in the supplemental NSPS proposal have been
submitted for approval to OMB under the PRA. The Information Collection Request (ICR)
document that the EPA prepared for this supplemental proposal has been assigned EPA ICR
number 2498.02. You can find a copy of the ICR in the docket for this rule, and it is briefly
summarized here.

       The information required to be collected is necessary to identify the regulated entities
subject to the proposed NSPS and to ensure their compliance with the proposed NSPS and this
supplemental proposal. The recordkeeping and reporting requirements are mandatory and are
being established under authority of CAA section 114 (42 U.S.C. 7414). All information other
than emissions data submitted as part of a report to the agency for which a claim of
confidentiality is made will be safeguarded according to CAA section 114(c) and the EPA's
implementing regulations at 40 CFR part 2, subpart B.

       The information collection requirements in the proposed NSPS (79 FR 41828,  July 17,
2014) were submitted for approval to OMB under the PRA. The ICR document that the EPA
prepared was assigned EPA ICR number 2498.01.  Since the NSPS review was  proposed on July
17, 2014, the EPA updated the number of existing  landfills likely to modify after July  17, 2014,
and, thus, become subject to proposed 40 CFR part 60, subpart XXX, as discussed in this
preamble. The supplemental proposal to lower the emission threshold for new and modified
sources affects the burden estimates the EPA presented in EPA ICR number 2498.01. As a result,
the EPA updated the EPA ICR number 2498.01 and re-submitted it to OMB for approval as EPA
ICR 2498.02 to reflect the estimated number of respondents and a lower NMOC emission rate. A
copy of the ICR is in Docket ID No. EPA-HQ-OAR-2003-0215, and it is briefly summarized
here.

       Respondents/affected entities: Municipal solid waste landfills that commence
       construction, reconstruction, or modification after July 17, 2014.
                                          8-3

-------
       Respondent's obligation to respond: Mandatory (40 CFR part 60, subpart XXX).

       Estimated number of respondents: 144 Municipal solid waste landfills that commence
       construction, reconstruction, or modification after July 17, 2014.

       Frequency of response: Initially, occasionally, and annually.

       Total estimated burden: 101,031 Hours (per year) for the responding facilities and 2,790
       hours (per year) for the agency. These are estimates for the average annual burden for the
       first 3 years after the rule is final. Burden is defined at 5 CFR 1320.3(b).

       Total estimated cost: $6,701,401 (per year), which includes annualized capital or
       operation and maintenance costs, for the responding facilities and $177,680 (per year) for
       the agency. These are estimates for the average annual cost for the first 3 years after the
       rule is final.

8.3   Regulatory Flexibility Act

       The Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA) generally requires an agency to prepare a
regulatory flexibility analysis of any rule subject to notice and comment rulemaking
requirements under the Administrative Procedure Act or any other statute unless the agency
certifies that the rule will not have a significant economic impact on a substantial number of
small entities (SISNOSE). Small entities include small businesses, small organizations, and small
governmental jurisdictions.

       For purposes of assessing the impacts of this proposed rule on small entities, small entity
is defined as: (1) a small business that is a small industrial entity as defined by the Small
Business Administration's (SBA) regulations at 13 CFR 121.201;  (2) a small governmental
jurisdiction that is a government of a city, county, town, school district or special district with a
population of less than 50,000; and (3) a small organization that is any not-for-profit enterprise
which is independently owned and operated and is not dominant in its field.
                                           8-4

-------
       After considering the economic impact of the proposed Emission Guidelines on small
entities, the EPA certifies that the proposed regulation will not have a Significant Impact on a
Substantial Number of Small Entities (SISNOSE).

       The proposed rule will not impose any requirements on small entities. Specifically,
Emission Guidelines established under CAA section 11 l(d) do not impose any requirements on
regulated entities and, thus, will not have a significant economic impact upon a substantial
number of small entities. After emission guidelines are promulgated, states and U.S. territories
establish standards on existing sources, and it is those requirements that could potentially impact
small entities.

       Our analysis here is consistent with the analysis of the analogous situation arising when
the EPA establishes NAAQS, which do not impose any requirements on regulated entities. As
here, any impact of a NAAQS on small entities would only arise when states take subsequent
action to maintain and/or achieve the NAAQS through their state implementation plans. See
American Trucking Associations v. EPA, 175 F.3d 1029, 1043-45 (D.C. Cir. 1999) (NAAQS do
not have significant impacts upon small entities because NAAQS themselves impose no
regulations upon small entities).

     After considering the economic impact of the supplemental proposed NSPS on small
entities, the analysis indicates that this rule will not have a significant impact on a substantial
number of small entities (SISNOSE). First, the proposed revision does not impact a substantial
number of small entities, since only 13 small entities are projected to be impacted by the
proposed option. Additionally, the impact to these entities are not significant, because only 2
entities have impacts greater than 1 percent of sales, and only 1 of these 2 entities has impacts
greater than 3 percent of sales. These results are summarized in Table 7-8.

8.4  Unfunded Mandates Reform Act

       Title H of the Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995 (UMRA), Public Law 104-4,
establishes requirements for federal agencies to assess the effects of their regulatory actions on
state, local, and tribal governments and the private sector. Under section 202 of the UMRA, the

                                          8-5

-------
EPA generally must prepare a written statement, including a cost-benefit analysis, for proposed
and final rules with "federal mandates" that may result in expenditures to state, local, and tribal
governments, in the aggregate, or to the private sector, of $100 million or more in any 1 year.
Before promulgating an EPA rule for which a written statement is needed, section 205 of the
UMRA generally requires the EPA to identify and consider a reasonable number of regulatory
alternatives and to adopt the least costly, most cost-effective or least burdensome alternative that
achieves the objectives of the rule. The provisions of section 205 do not apply when they are
inconsistent with applicable law. Moreover, section 205 allows the EPA to adopt an alternative
other than the least costly, most cost-effective or least burdensome alternative if the
Administrator publishes with the final rule an explanation for why that alternative was not
adopted. Before the EPA establishes any regulatory requirements that may significantly or
uniquely affect small governments, including tribal governments, it must have developed under
section 203 of the UMRA a small government agency plan. The plan must provide for notifying
potentially affected small governments, enabling officials of affected small governments to have
meaningful and timely input in the development of the EPA regulatory proposals with significant
federal intergovernmental mandates, and informing, educating, and advising small governments
on compliance with the regulatory requirements.

       This action does not contain any unfunded mandate of $100 million or more as described
in UMRA, 2 U.S.C. 1531-1538. The proposed Emission Guidelines apply to landfills that were
constructed, modified, or reconstructed on or after November 8, 1987, and that commenced
construction, reconstruction, or modification on or before July 17, 2014. Impacts resulting from
the proposed Emission Guidelines are below the applicable threshold.

       However, the proposed Emission Guidelines may significantly or uniquely affect small
governments because small governments operate landfills. The EPA consulted with small
governments concerning the regulatory requirements that might significantly or uniquely affect
them. In developing this rule, the EPA consulted with small governments pursuant to a plan
established under section 203 of the UMRA to address impacts of regulatory requirements in the
rule that might significantly or uniquely affect small governments. The EPA held meetings as
discussed in Section 7.5 under Federalism  consultations.

                                          8-6

-------
       The supplemental proposal for the NSPS does not contain a federal mandate that may
result in expenditures of $100 million or more for state, local, and tribal governments, in the
aggregate, or the private sector in any one year. This action applies to landfills that were
constructed, modified, or reconstructed on or after July 17, 2014. Impacts resulting from the
proposed NSPS are far below the applicable threshold. Thus, the proposed NSPS is not subject to
the requirements of sections 202 or 205 of the UMRA.

8.5   Executive Order 13132:  Federalism

       Executive Order 13132,  entitled "Federalism" (64 FR 43255, August 10, 1999), requires
the EPA to develop an accountable process to ensure "meaningful and timely input by  state and
local officials in the development of regulatory policies that have federalism implications."
"Policies that have federalism implications" are defined in the Executive Order to include
regulations that have "substantial direct effects on the states, on the relationship between the
national government and the states, or on the distribution of power and responsibilities among
the various levels of government." The EPA has concluded that the proposed Emission
Guidelines have federalism implications, because the rule imposes substantial direct compliance
costs on state or local governments, and the federal government will not provide the funds
necessary to pay those costs.

       The EPA has concluded that the supplemental proposal for the NSPS does not have
Federalism implications. The proposed NSPS will not have substantial direct effects on the
states, on the relationship between the national government and the states, or on the distribution
of power and responsibilities among the various levels of government, as specified in Executive
Order 13132. The supplemental proposal will not have impacts of $25 million or more in any
one year. Thus, Executive Order 13132 does  not apply to the supplemental. Although section 6
of Executive Order 13132 does not apply to the supplemental proposal NSPS, the EPA consulted
with state and local officials and representatives of state and local governments early in the
process of developing the proposed rules for MSW landfills (both the NSPS and Emission
Guidelines) to permit them to have meaningful and timely input  into the rules' development. The
EPA conducted a Federalism Consultation Outreach Meeting on September 10, 2013. Due to
interest in that meeting, additional outreach meetings were held on November 7, 2013 and
                                          8-7

-------
November 14, 2013. With the pending proposal of these Emission Guidelines, an additional
Federalism outreach meeting was conducted on April 15, 2015. Participants included the
National Governors' Association, the National Conference of State Legislatures, the Council of
State Governments, the National League of Cities, the U.S. Conference of Mayors, the National
Association of Counties, the International City/County Management Association, the National
Association of Towns and Townships, the County Executives of America, the Environmental
Council of States, National Association of Clean Air Agencies, Association of State and
Territorial Solid Waste Management Officials, environmental agency representatives from 43
states, and approximately 60 representatives from city and county governments. The comment
period was extended to  allow sufficient time for interested parties to review briefing materials
and provide comments.  Concerns raised during the consultations include: implementation
concerns associated with shortening of gas collection system installation and/or expansion
timeframes, concerns regarding significant lowering of the design capacity or emission
thresholds, the need for clarifications associated with wellhead operating parameters and the
need for consistent, clear and rigorous surface monitoring requirements.

8.6  Executive Order 13175: Consultation and Coordination with Indian Tribal
     Governments

       Executive Order 13175, entitled "Consultation and Coordination with Indian Tribal
Governments" (65 FR 67249, November 9, 2000), requires the EPA to develop an accountable
process to ensure "meaningful and timely input by tribal officials in the development of
regulatory policies that have tribal implications." This action has tribal implications. However,  it
will neither impose substantial direct compliance costs on federally recognized tribal
governments, nor preempt tribal law. The database used to estimate impacts of the proposed 40
CFR part 60,  subpart Cf identified one tribe, the Salt River Pima-Maricopa Indian Community,
which owns three landfills potentially  subject to the proposed Emission Guidelines. One of these
landfills is open, the Salt River Landfill, and is already controlling emissions under the current
NSPS/EG framework, so while subject to this subpart, the costs of this proposal are not
substantial. The two other landfills are closed and anticipated to meet the definition of the closed
landfill  subcategory. One of the landfills, the Tri Cities Landfill is already controlling emissions

-------
under the current NSPS/EG framework and will not incur substantial additional compliance costs
under Cf. The other landfill, North Center Street Landfill, is not estimated to install controls
under the current NSPS/EG framework.

       The supplemental NSPS proposal does not have tribal implications, as specified in
Executive Order 13175. Based on the EPA's review of existing landfills as outlined in the
docketed memorandum, "Summary of Landfill Dataset Used in the Cost and Emission Reduction
Analysis of Landfills Regulations. 2014," tribal landfills are not anticipated to be large enough to
become subject to the rulemaking. Thus, Executive Order 13175 does not apply to the
supplemental NSPS proposal. Nevertheless, the EPA specifically solicits comment on this action
from tribal officials.

8.7   Executive Order 13045: Protection of Children from  Environmental Health Risks
      and Safety Risks

       Executive Order 13045, "Protection of Children from Environmental Health Risks and
Safety Risks" (62 FR 19885, April 23, 1997) applies to any rule that: (1) is determined to be
"economically significant" as defined under Executive Order 12866, and (2) concerns an
environmental health or safety risk that the EPA has reason to believe may have a
disproportionate effect on children. If the regulatory action meets both criteria, the Agency must
evaluate the environmental health or safety effects of the planned rule on children, and explain
why the planned regulation is preferable to other potentially effective and reasonably feasible
alternatives considered by the Agency.

       The EPA interprets Executive Order 13045 as applying only to those regulatory actions
that concern environmental health or safety risks that the EPA has reason to believe may
disproportionately affect children, per the definition of "covered regulatory action" in section 2-
202 of the Executive Order. The proposed Emission Guidelines and the supplemental NSPS
proposal are not subject to Executive Order 13045 because they do not concern an environmental
health risk or safety risk. We also note that the methane and NMOC reductions expected from
the proposed Emission Guidelines and NSPS will have positive health effects including for
children as previously discussed in Chapter 4.
                                          8-9

-------
8.8  Executive Order 13211:  Actions Concerning Regulations That Significantly Affect
     Energy Supply, Distribution, or Use

       This proposed action is not a "significant energy action" as defined in Executive Order
13211, "Actions Concerning Regulations That Significantly Affect Energy Supply, Distribution,
or Use" (66 FR 28355 (May 22, 2001)) because in the Agency's judgment it is not likely to have
a significant adverse effect on the supply, distribution, or use of energy. The EPA has concluded
that this rule is not likely to have any adverse energy effects because there are a small number of
landfills subject to control requirements under subpart Cf Further, the EPA has concluded that
the proposed Emission Guidelines and supplemental NSPS proposal are not likely to have any
adverse energy effects because the energy demanded to operate these control systems will be
offset by additional energy supply from landfill gas energy projects.

8.9  National Technology Transfer and Advancement Act

       Section 12(d) of the National Technology Transfer and Advancement Act of 1995
(NTTAA), Public Law No. 104-113, §12(d) (15 U.S.C. 272 note) directs the EPA to use
voluntary consensus standards in its regulatory activities unless to do so would be inconsistent
with applicable law or otherwise impractical. Voluntary consensus standards are technical
standards (e.g., materials specifications, test methods, sampling procedures, and business
practices) that are developed or adopted by voluntary consensus standards bodies. The NTTAA
directs the EPA to provide Congress, through OMB, explanations when the Agency decides not
to use available and applicable voluntary consensus standards.

       This action involves technical standards. The EPA has decided to use EPA Methods 2,
2E, 3, 3A, 3C, 21, 25, 25A, and  25C of 40 CFR part 60, appendix A. While the EPA identified
10 VCS as being potentially applicable (ANSI/ASME PTC 19-10-1981  Part 10, ASME B133.9-
1994 (2001), ISO 10396:1993 (2007), ISO 12039:2001, ASTMD5835-95 (2013), ASTM
D6522-11, CAN/CSAZ223.2-M86 (1999), ASTMD6060-96 (2009), ISO 14965:2000(E), EN
12619(1999)), the agency decided not to use these methods. The EPA determined that the 10
candidate VCS identified for measuring emissions of pollutants or their surrogates subject to
emission standards in the rule would not be practical due to lack of equivalency, documentation,
                                         8-10

-------
validation data, and other important technical and policy considerations. The agency identified
no such standards for Methods 2E, 21, and 25C. The EPA's review, including review comments
for these 10 methods, is documented in the memorandum, "Voluntary Consensus Standard
Results for Emission Guidelines and Compliance Times for Municipal Solid Waste Landfills" in
the docket for this rulemaking.

8.10 Executive Order 12898:  Environmental Justice

       Executive Order 12898 (59 FR 7629 (Feb. 16, 1994)) establishes federal executive policy
on environmental justice. Its main provision directs federal agencies, to the greatest extent
practicable and permitted by law, to make environmental justice part of their mission by
identifying and addressing, as appropriate, disproportionately high and adverse human health or
environmental effects of their programs, policies, and activities on minority populations and low
income populations in the United States.

       To gain a better understanding of the Municipal Solid Waste Landfills source category
and near-source populations,  the EPA conducted a proximity analysis at a study area of 3 miles
of the source category for this rulemaking. This analysis identifies, on a limited basis, the
subpopulations that may be exposed to  air pollution from the regulated sources and thus are
expected to benefit most from this regulation. This analysis does not identify the demographic
characteristics of the most highly affected individuals or communities, nor does it quantify the
level of risk faced by those individuals  or communities.  To the extent that any minority, low-
income or indigenous subpopulation is  disproportionately impacted by hazardous air emissions
due to the proximity of their homes to sources of these emissions, that subpopulation also stands
to see increased environmental and health benefit from the emission reductions called for by this
rule.

       The EPA believes the human health or environmental  risk addressed by this action will
not have potential disproportionately high and adverse human health or environmental effects on
minority, low-income or indigenous populations because the proposed subpart would reduce
emissions of landfill gas, which contains both nonmethane organic compounds and methane.
These avoided emissions will improve air quality and reduce public health and welfare  effects
                                         8-11

-------
associated with exposure to landfill gas emissions. The results of the proximity analysis
conducted for the proposed Emission Guidelines are presented in the April 22, 2015 document
entitled, "2015 Environmental Justice Screening Report for Municipal Solid Waste Landfills," a
copy of which is available in the docket (Docket ID No. EPA-HQ-OAR-2003-0215).

       In regards to the supplemental landfills NSPS proposal, the EPA has concluded that it is
not practicable to determine whether there would be disproportionately high and adverse human
health or environmental effects on minority, low income, or indigenous populations from this
proposed rule because it is unknown where new or modified facilities will be located. However,
the previously mentioned proximity analysis conducted for the proposed Emission Guidelines
provides information about the populations likely to be impacted.
                                         8-12

-------
United States                         Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards         Publication No. EPA-452/R-15-008
Environmental Protection               Health and Environmental Impacts Division                             August 2015
Agency                                     Research Triangle Park, NC

-------