United States	National Center for	EPA-236-B-15-001
Environmental Protection	Environmental Economics	December 9, 2020
Agency	Office of Policy
Washington DC 20460
<>EPA Handbook on Valuing
Changes in Time Use
Induced by Regulatory
Requirements and
Other EPA Actions

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
Acknowledgements
This Handbook was developed by U.S. EPA's National Center for Environmental Economics
(NCEE) in the Office of Policy (OP) with primary participants: Ann Ferris, Robin R Jenkins and
William Wheeler. This document benefited from both internal (EPA) and external peer review.
Comments on prior drafts were provided by Chris Dockins and Matt Massey, both in EPA's NCEE,
and by members of EPA's Economics Forum. An external peer review panel provided invaluable
suggestions in developing this Handbook. Dietrich Earnhart (University of Kansas), Adriana
Kugler (Georgetown University) and James Staudt (Andover Technology) served as members of
the peer review panel. For a summary of the external peer review, please contact Robin Jenkins
at jenkins.robin@epa.gov. Chapter 8 of the forthcoming revised EPA's Guidelines for Preparing
Economic Analysis contains guidance for valuing time use changes based on details provided in
this document.

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
Table of Contents
Acknowledgements	ii
Acronyms and Abbreviations	v
Introduction	1
1.	The Need to Value Time Use Changes	1
2.	Conceptual Foundations	3
2.1	Nomenclature	4
2.2	Work Time	5
2.3	Non-work Time	6
2.4	Valuing Time for ICRs	8
3.	Practical Approach	9
3.1	Operating Assumptions	9
3.2	Estimating the Value of Work Time: The Full Employer Costs of Labor Time	9
3.3	Estimating the Value of Non-work Time	10
3.4	Data and Calculations	11
3.5	Summary	13
4.	Considerations and Limitations	15
4.1	The Potential for Double-Counting	15
4.2	Transfer Payments as Proxy for Social Costs	16
4.3	Quasi-fixed Cost Models	16
4.4	Opportunity Cost of Non-work Time	17
Appendix A	18
Appendix B	30
Appendix C	31
References	32

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
List of Figures
Figure 2.1 - Labor Market	3
Figure 2.2 - Firms' Demand for Labor	5
Figure 2.3 - Labor-Leisure Trade-Off	6
List of Tables
Table 3.1 - Estimating Time Costs for EPA Regulatory Impact Analyses and ICRs	14
List of Text Boxes
Text Box 4.1 - Examples of Potential Double-Counting	15
iv

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
Acronyms and Abbreviations
BLS	Bureau of Labor Statistics
CPS	Current Population Survey
CWSS	Community Water System Survey
DOL	Department of Labor
DOT	Department of Transportation
ECEC	Employer Costs for Employee Compensation
EIA	economic impact analysis
EPA	Environmental Protection Agency
GAO.	Government Accountability Office
HHS	Department of Health and Human Services
ICR	information collection request
NCEE	National Center for Environmental Economics
NCS	National Compensation Survey
OEI	Office of Environmental Information
OES	Occupational Employment Statistics
OMB	Office of Management and Budget
OP	Office of Policy
RACER....Remedial Action Cost Engineering Requirements
RIA	regulatory impact analysis

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
Introduction
This document describes how to value changes in time use due to compliance and information
provision activities induced by Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) regulatory requirements.
Such values inform social cost estimates in benefit-cost analysis, and burden estimates that
support information collection requests (ICRs).
This document begins with an explanation of the need for valuing time use changes at EPA, then
presents conceptual foundations, and offers practical estimation approaches and data sources for
valuing work time and non-work time. The discussion draws from two U.S Department of Health
and Human Services (HHS) documents (2016, 2017) and relies on other sources as well. A brief
examination of recent EPA practice with examples of time use values calculated for past EPA
analyses is included.
The approach described in this document differs from how environmental economists value time
invested in recreational activities,1 but is similar though not identical to the methods recommended
in EPA's Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analysis (2014) to estimate the value of time lost
due to illness in cost-of-illness estimates.2 These alternative scenarios that require estimating
time values are typically encountered during benefits analysis. Chapter 7 of EPA's Guidelines for
Preparing Economic Analyses (2014) contains more information.
1. The Need to Value Time Use Changes
To advance the agency's mission to protect human health and the environment, EPA regulations
induce changes in the use of productive resources including people's time. Often, these changes
occur at the workplace, where labor is required to undertake pollution control activities such as
record-keeping and reporting requirements. Sometimes, the use of time outside of the workplace
may be affected; for example, product bans might cause consumers to switch to substitute
products that require larger investments of time. Other examples of time use that might change
due to compliance activities include:
•	Training
•	Familiarization with new regulation
•	Pollution monitoring
•	Inspections
•	Installation, operation and maintenance of pollution control equipment
1	By convention, time invested in recreational activities is valued at one-third of an hourly wage rate. For examples, see Amoako-Tuffour
and Martinez-Espineira (2012), Fezzi, et al. (2014) and Heagney, et al. (2019).
2	See Chapter 7 in U.S. EPA (2014). The Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analysis recommend using the "worker's wages and employment
benefit values" to estimate the value of lost work time and using "after-tax wages" to estimate the value of lost time spent on non-
market work and leisure activities. A different approach, called the replacement cost approach, is sometimes used in the cost of illness
literature to estimate the value of reductions in time spent in household production. The replacement cost approach values time at the
cost of purchasing matched activities through the marketplace, e.g., house cleaning services (Lakdawalla, et al. 2018).
1

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
These changes in time use are often an important component of the social costs of a regulation
(OMB 2003). They are also important to cost savings. For example, the Hazardous Waste
Electronic Manifest (e-Manifest) rule that introduced the option to file hazardous waste manifests
electronically rather than only by paper, was estimated to save significant amounts of record-
keeping time. Changes in time use are also important to agency analyses of the financial burdens
posed by ICRs which typically include the private costs of work or non-work time.
The U.S. Government Accountability Office (GAO) finds variability in federal agency practices for
estimating the time costs of ICRs (GAO 2018).3 GAO concludes that many ICRs submitted by
agencies to the Office of Management and Budget (OMB), and subsequently approved, did not
estimate the value of burden hours as required by OMB. In cases in which values were estimated,
fringe benefits were inconsistently included in the calculations. GAO also finds a lack of clear
guidance from OMB regarding approaches for estimating time costs, for ICRs and otherwise.
OMB briefly considers the topic in Regulatory Impact Analysis: Frequently Asked Questions
(2011), stating that agencies should monetize time costs and cost-savings in regulatory impact
analyses (RIAs); the conceptually correct measure is the opportunity cost of time; and the average
wage of affected workers can serve as a proxy.
More recently, HHS has published two peer-reviewed documents (2016, 2017) — guidelines
and a detailed report — that address the value of time for HHS regulatory impact analyses. The
documents include a conceptual framework, a review of related literature on the value of time
in the recreation demand and transportation economics literatures and a description of best
practices at HHS. The U.S. Department of Transportation (DOT) provides guidance (DOT 2016),
updated regularly, specifically on the valuation of travel time.
Within EPA, recent practice for valuing time-use changes for cost analyses and ICRs has some
variability. Appendix A provides examples of program-specific instruction documents and past
analyses and summarizes each document's approach to estimating the value of work-time,
including the total adjustment to the wage rate to capture additional costs of employment to
the employer.4 There is one example offered of the value of non-work time. The variation in the
estimates of work time is often appropriate, as the estimates depend on the industries and
occupations of affected workers. However, there is also variation as to whether and how analysts
included not only employee fringe benefits but also other indirect, or overhead, costs.
The framework and best practices described here draw heavily from HHS (2016, 2017), taking
into consideration recent EPA estimated values and valuation approaches, and with additional
sources, some that are especially relevant to the context of EPA regulations. The recommended
best practices rely on estimates of wages, fringe benefits, additional employer costs of
employment and taxes on earned income paid by workers. The best practices appear in Chapter
8 of the forthcoming revised EPA's Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analysis.
3	GAO examines practices by four agencies that impose the greatest ICR burden hours: Internal Revenue Service and the U.S. Departments
of Health and Human Services, Agriculture, and Transportation.
4	These analyses were readily accessible and do not reflect a representative sample.
2

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
2. Conceptual Foundations
The social cost of resources that are used to comply with regulation is equal to their opportunity
cost. The opportunity cost of time depends on the availability of options and the perspective
of the person facing the choice (Feldstein 1978). In long-run equilibrium, the economy is at
full employment (everyone who wants a job is employed at prevailing market wages) and the
distribution of time between work and non-work is at a steady state. As will be explained, a variety
of market distortions affect the value of work time and non-work time. The employer's perspective
should be used to value work time because they decide how to allocate labor at the workplace.
Based on the first-order conditions of the employer's optimal selection of the quantity of labor,
the marginal cost of using one more unit of labor equals the marginal revenue generated by
employing that additional unit of labor to generate additional product.
Employers usually value an additional hour of work differently than workers would. An important
reason for this difference is that employers pay labor taxes that are not part of workers' hourly
earnings (wages) such as unemployment insurance and their portion of Social Security. In
addition, workers generally must pay labor taxes according to their earnings (e.g., their own
share of Social Security as well as federal and state income taxes). Figure 2.1 illustrates a market
supply-demand model in which labor taxes drive a wedge between the wage that firms pay and
the lower wage that workers receive.
Labor supply
Rate firms pay
Wage without taxes
a>
O)
S
TAX WEDGE -
Wage workers take home
Labor demand
Quantity of Labor
Figure 2.1 - Labor Market
Adapted from Manns (2015), Figure 8.
Figure 2.1 highlights the tax wedge between employee and employer opportunity costs. This simple illustration considers only two
costs of labor: wages and taxes. It shows that in a setting with zero taxes the opportunity costs faced by employers and employees
are the same and equal to the "Wage without taxes." In practice, both employers and employees pay taxes. Employers must pay taxes
for each worker and will hire workers until the last one hired is valued by an amount equal to the wage plus the employer tax rate.
Thus, the employer's opportunity cost of a worker's time is higher than the wage rate without taxes and instead equals the "Rate firms
pay." Employees must pay their own taxes and thus do not take home the full amount of the wages earned. Therefore, the employee's
opportunity cost of their own time is lower than the wage rate without taxes and instead equals the "Wage workers take home."
3

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
The opportunity cost of work time differs from the opportunity cost of non-work time for additional
reasons, including that employers often face costs Peyond wages and taxes, such as overhead
costs, to support the labor they employ. Pre-existing market distortions, such as inflexible work
schedules, can further differentiate the opportunity cost of work time compared to non-work time.
The value of non-work time is measured from the perspective of households or individuals, some
of whom work for pay, and others who do not. For households or individuals, the opportunity cost
of time depends on the opportunity cost of foregone alternative activities. These activities include
a wide range of possibilities from household production to leisure to work.
2.1 Nomenclature
To explain how the opportunity cost of time differs between employers and employees, this
document distinguishes between categories of expenses associated with labor. These categories
include wages, taxes, benefits and more. The following definitions provide a nomenclature for the
remainder of the document.
Wages: The monetary compensation paid to employees for their time at work either as an hourly
wage or salary.
Fringe Benefits: Categories of employer expenses on labor that provide in-kind or
monetary benefits to workers beyond wages and salaries. BLS divides these categories into
two broad groups:
Voluntary Benefits: Categories of employer-paid benefits including paid leave,
supplemental pay (e.g., for overtime), insurance and retirement and savings plans.
Legally Required Benefits: Categories of employer-paid benefits that employers
are legally required to pay for, including Social Security, Medicare, unemployment
insurance and workers' compensation. Many sources refer to these expenses as
employers' payroll taxes.
Overhead: Employer costs associated with labor, but not paid directly to workers, such as the
value of personnel services, training activities and employee office space. Some sources refer to
these expenses as indirect costs.
Taxes on Earned Income: Tax payments made by workers to federal, state or local government
on their earned income, sometimes subject to earnings limits. They include income taxes, and
employees' portions of Social Security and Medicare.
4

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
2.2 Work Time
Work time is time spent in activities for which monetary payment is received. The opportunity
cost of work time is determined by the value of the marginal product that would have been
produced if not for the regulatory activity. To maximize profits, employers hire labor until their
cost at the margin equals the value of what is produced, or the marginal revenue product.
Figure 2.2 illustrates the firm's choice reflecting the typical assumption of diminishing marginal
product of labor.
a>
3
C
a>
ro o
.Eii
a>
L.
CO
2
Number of Workers
Figure 2.2 - Firms' Demand for Labor
Adapted from Ehrenberg and Smith (2012), Figure 3.2, p 68.
Figure 2.2 shows the firm's demand curve for labor assuming diminishing marginal returns to labor. The quantity of employees
demanded by firms depends on the marginal revenue product associated with each additional worker hired.
This suggests that a proxy for the opportunity cost of work time is the cost to employers of
workers' time. This consists of the entire cost of employing the worker — including wages
and fringe benefits, as well as overhead costs needed to enable the worker to be productive,
such as the value of personnel services, training activities and employee office space. Under
ideal conditions of perfect competition and the absence of marketplace distortions, the cost to
employers would equal the social opportunity cost of work time.
Note, however, that the cost to employers of workers' time is an imperfect proxy for the
opportunity cost of work time. Due to market distortions such as monopoly in the product market
or monopsony in the labor market, marginal revenue product or the value of foregone production
to the employer will sometimes differ from the value of foregone production to the consumer. The
latter is the social opportunity cost that is the goal for measurement.
Social costs differ from private costs because they represent values placed by society, rather than
by a single firm. The final users of a product who express a willingness to pay for it determine
the perspective of society. For example, for a monopolist, the marginal revenue product
associated with a unit of input is lower than its social opportunity cost, since additional production
reduces price. Thus, the monopolist constrains output below the level that would occur under
5

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
perfect competition. Note that these market distortions drive a wedge Petween the marginal
revenue product and the value of output to consumers, or the social opportunity cost (this is
distinct from the wedge driven Py taxes Petween employer and employee opportunity costs
previously descriPed).
2.3 Non-work Time
In some cases, a regulation may change how individuals use time outside of paid work time.
This time is called non-work time, or often within the economics literature, it is called leisure.
This is time that may be spent carrying out nonmarket tasks, recreating, sleeping or engaging
in a host of other activities. The opportunity cost of non-work time may vary by the activities
foregone; the desirability or distastefulness of the activity that occupies time; whether workers
have a continuous choice over the number of hours of paid work; socioeconomic characteristics
of affected individuals; and other factors. Thus, there is great variability in the opportunity cost of
non-work time. The economics literature recognizes this, and it likely contributes to the lack of
consensus on a valuation approach.
The neoclassical theory of labor supply begins with a simplifying assumption that an individual is
endowed with time and can then choose to spend some of that time working to earn income with
which to buy consumer goods. The amount of non-work time or leisure that they choose could
have alternatively been spent working and earning income, so the individual is in a sense "buying"
leisure and the earnings rate is leisure's opportunity cost. Figure 2.3 illustrates the individual's
optimal choice as the point of tangency between the budget line and indifference curve between
earnings and leisure time.
a>
E
o
o
c
80 60 40 20 0 Hours of Paid Work per Week
0 20 40 60 80 Hours of Leisure per Week
Figure 2.3 - Labor-Leisure Trade-Off
Adapted from Ehrenberg and Smith (2012), Figures 6.4 and 6.5, p. 179.
Figure 2.3 illustrates the trade-off faced by individuals between time spent working versus non-work time (also known as leisure),
known as the labor-leisure trade-off. In the figure, the optimal choices for Individuals 1 and 2 are the points of tangency between the
individuals' indifference curves and the budget line that is constrained by a time endowment. Individual 1 maximizes utility by choosing
to work 40 hours per week while Individual 2 prefers to work less than 40 hours. In practice, many jobs are offered with a fixed number
of hours that often will not allow employees full flexibility in choosing an optimal number of hours to work. In the figure, both workers
accept the 40-hour work week despite their different preferences regarding optimal leisure time.
6

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
The labor-leisure trade-off is a standard economic assumption suggesting that individuals
who can freely choose their hours of work will work until the point at which the earnings from
an additional hour of work no longer offset the value of an hour of leisure time. In Figure 2.3,
Individual 1, represented by both prefers and chooses to work 40 hours per week. However,
in many cases the standard 40-hour work week causes suboptimal outcomes. Individual 2,
represented by U2, is constrained by the standard 40-hour work week. Individual 2 chooses to
work 40 hours even though he or she prefers to work less than 40 hours.5
Employee earnings include wages minus taxes on earned income, plus voluntary fringe benefits.
Legally required benefits6 are excluded since they are not freely chosen; that is, they are further
removed from the efficiencies created by free markets than voluntary fringe benefit categories.
This suggests one straightforward and accessible measure of the opportunity cost of leisure or
non-work time is the value of foregone earnings. This includes the opportunity cost of time for
individuals not employed in the labor force since, conceptually, they make a similar choice to value
non-work time more highly than potential earnings.
Studies on the value of time to individuals and households consist of many variations; for reviews,
see Gonzalez (1997), Phaneuf and Till (2016) and Jara-Diaz and Rosales-Salas (2017). In general,
the standard framework omits the utility or disutility experienced from work so that the value of
non-work time is equal to marginal earnings. The value of non-work time may exceed the marginal
earnings if the worker experiences additional utility from working, for example, a worker who
experiences satisfaction on top of receiving wages. Alternatively, the value of non-work time may
be less than marginal earnings after accounting for costs of commuting, child care or other costs
associated with employment or if the worker experiences disutility from working, for example, a
worker who experiences dread while at work. These subtleties highlight the difficulties in valuing
non-work time and the importance of individual preferences. If regulatory or information collection
requirements are perceived as particularly distasteful, this may affect time costs.
Despite these considerations, the labor-leisure trade-off is a solid foundation for the value of
non-work time. The labor-leisure trade-off is an underpinning to EPA's Guidelines for Preparing
Economic Analyses (2014), which describes EPA's approach for valuing time spent on non-market
work and leisure activities based on the concept of opportunity cost (EPA 2014). HHS guidance
(2016, 2017) also offers a conceptual framework that rests on the labor-leisure trade-off.
EPA (2005) and HHS (2016, 2017) suggest estimating the opportunity cost of non-work time as
wages minus taxes on earned income, without including the value of voluntary fringe benefits or
the costs associated with employment such as commuting or child care. The assumption is that
individuals focus on their potential take-home pay. HHS (2017) admits that this assumption is
5	Note that most labor market participants would be to the left or right of the tangency in the labor supply graph in Figure 2.3, and only a
portion would be precisely at the point of tangency. Because most labor market participants work more than only a few hours a week,
they are not close to the corner point (at zero hours of work) of the labor-leisure budget constraint, where labor market participation is a
"yes" or "no" decision.
6	Legally required benefits are defined above and include categories of benefits that employers are legally required to pay for, including
the employer's share of Social Security, Medicare, unemployment insurance and workers' compensation.
7

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
"particularly uncertain" in the case of people who are not workforce participants. This Handbook
suggests in Section 3, below, that EPA analysts should include the voluntary portion of employer-
paid fringe benefit values in addition to after-tax wages to estimate the opportunity cost of non-
work time. The reason is that fringe benefits are clearly valuable. Thus, an individual would include
them when assessing the labor-leisure choice.
Wages minus taxes on earned income, plus voluntary benefits, only approximate the value of non-
work time. Most people do not have fully flexible working hours; for example, many jobs require
a standard 40-hour week. In Figure 2.3, to maximize utility Individual 2 would prefer to work less
than 40 hours but is constrained by the standard work week. For Individual 2, the value of the
marginal hour of leisure exceeds the wage rate. Empirical papers have examined the effect of
inflexibility in work hours and have found both that the opportunity cost of leisure time may be less
than or greater than the earnings rate, depending on whether individuals wished to work more
or fewer hours.
More broadly, there is a significant amount of empirical research that has applied stated and
revealed preference methods to estimate the value of time in recreation and transportation
activities. Findings vary substantially. For example, Lloyd-Smith (2019) analyzes a stated
preference survey and finds that the value of leisure time differs substantially across individuals
and not according to their wage rate. Small (2012) conducts a selective review of the value of
travel time and reports that past research has found the willingness to pay for time savings to
be related to a wide variety of factors, including: time-of-day choices, length of time savings,
income or wage rate and unpleasantness of circumstances such as traffic congestion. The paper
concludes that the "behavioral regularities" behind human trade-offs between time and money are
"subtle and complex" and more work is needed to better understand them.7
2.4 Valuing Time for ICRs
In general, this Handbook recommends the same estimation approach for valuing time for an
ICR as for a benefit-cost analysis. On its face, the value of time useful for estimating social costs
within a benefit-cost analysis might differ from the value useful for ICR burden estimates. Their
conceptual underpinnings differ. The objective for benefit-cost analysis is to estimate costs to
society while the objective for an ICR is to estimate the extent of paperwork burden on private
individuals. However, as explained above, the best proxies for estimating the social values of work
time and non-work time are private costs.
7 See Small (2012), pp. 11 -12. See also DOT (2016) or HHS (2017) for a review of the literature addressing the value of
travel time savings.
8

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
3. Practical Approach
This section outlines a practical approach for valuing work time and non-work time for regulatory
and ICR analyses. The conclusions reached appear in Chapter 8 of EPA's forthcoming revised
Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analysis.
3.1 Operating Assumptions
EPA largely follows the practical approach in HHS (2016, 2017) with some minor divergences. The
approach includes four operating assumptions:
1)	Regulatory activities at work displace other paid work (at the regulated workplace or
elsewhere); regulatory activities during non-work time displace other unpaid activities.
2)	Average or median estimates appropriately measure the value of a marginal unit of time over
the range expected to be affected by a regulation.
3)	The value of activities conducted during paid work time can be approximated by the cost of
labor to the employer. Employer costs include wages, fringe benefits and associated labor
overhead costs.
4)	The opportunity cost of non-work time can be approximated by wages minus taxes on earned
income, plus the portion of fringe benefits that is voluntary.8
3.2 Estimating the Value of Work Time: The Full Employer
Costs of Labor Time
The value of work time consists of three categories of employer labor costs: wages, fringe
benefits and overhead costs. The values of these components vary by firm, industry, region,
occupation and additional factors. For best practices, estimates of employer costs should be as
specific as possible to the workers asked to complete the required tasks (OMB 2011). Data are
often available to account for both occupation and industry.
Typically, there is a disparity between employers' average and marginal costs of labor. Figure 2.2
illustrates the typical assumption of declining marginal productivity of labor and shows that the
firm's valuation of the marginal unit of labor is declining. However, accessible labor cost estimates
almost always represent average, not marginal, values. Thus, in practice, averages are used to
represent marginal values.
To estimate the full employer costs of labor time, begin with an industry- and/or occupation-
specific wage. The wage rate should be adjusted upward to account for fringe benefits and
overhead costs as shown by Equation (1).
(1) Employer costs of labor = Wages + Fringe benefits + Overhead costs
Estimates of fringe benefits and overhead costs should also be industry- and/or occupation-
specific whenever possible.
8 This assumption differs from HHS (2016, 2017) by including voluntary fringe benefits.
9

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
The categories of costs to be included in fringe benefits (HHS 2017; BLS 2019) are:
•	Paid leave (vacation, holiday, sick, personal)
•	Supplemental pay (overtime and premium, shift differentials, nonproduction bonuses)
•	Insurance (life, health, short- and long-term disability)
•	Retirement and savings (defined benefit, defined contribution)
•	Legally required benefits (Social Security and Medicare, federal and state unemployment
insurance and workers' compensation) (BLS 2019a, HHS 2017)
The categories of costs to be included in overhead costs (referred to as "indirect" costs by HHS)
should be directly connected to hiring, evaluating, providing workspace, training and otherwise
supporting employees. HHS (2017) describes these categories as reflecting the resources
necessary for the administrative oversight of employees and generally include:
•	time spent on administrative personnel issues (e.g., human resources activities such as hiring,
performance reviews, personnel transfers, affirmative action programs)
•	time spent writing administrative guidance documents
•	office expenses (e.g., space rental, utilities, equipment costs)
•	outreach and general training (e.g., employee development) (HHS 2017)
3.3 Estimating the Value of Non-work Time
The individual's perspective should be adopted to estimate the value of non-work time. The labor-
leisure trade-off suggests that the opportunity cost to individuals of non-work time is the value of
potential work time. There is readily available data on the value of voluntary fringe benefits;9 thus, to
estimate the value of non-work time, analysts should use an individual's potential earnings, defined
as wages minus taxes on earned income, plus voluntary fringe benefits, as shown by Equation (2).
(2) Individual's value of time = (Wages - Taxes on earned income) + Voluntary fringe benefits
Analysts should use estimates that are most appropriate for the affected population which
may include industry- or occupation-specific values. Often, however, analysts may not have
information regarding an industry or occupation affiliation for the affected population. For example,
affected individuals may be in a variety of different occupations and industries or not working at
all. This includes the possibility that individuals are either unemployed or not participating in the
labor force. In these cases, analysts should use averages reflecting the region where the affected
population is located or, if the regulation affects households nationwide, national averages. The
portion of fringe benefits that are voluntary may include paid leave, supplemental pay, insurance
and retirement and savings benefits.
9 See BLS Employer Costs of Employee Compensation (ECEC) at https://www.bls.gov/news.release/ecec.toc.htm
10

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
Analysts who have information regarding the desirability or distastefulness of time costs faced by
households from regulatory or information collection requirements should qualitatively describe
why such preferences may increase or decrease the opportunity cost of time. For example, if
requirements involve onerous tasks, analysts might highlight that this would increase time costs;
or if they involve pleasant tasks, analysts might describe that this would decrease time costs.
3.4 Data and Calculations
BLS and the U.S. Census Bureau publish data on industry- and occupation-specific wage rates,
as well as regional or population-wide wage rates, for civilian workers including those in the
private sector and state and local government.10 To estimate fringe benefits, industry specific
data is recommended, and a useful source is BLS Employer Costs for Employee Compensation
(ECEC). For example, for manufacturing, the BLS ECEC June 2020 report indicates an average
ratio of fringe benefits to wages of 0.51.11 The BLS ECEC also contains data on fringe benefits
and wages for state and local government workers.12 The national average ratio of fringe benefits
to wages is reported by the BLS ECEC and could be used when a nationwide estimate is needed.
The national average ratio in June 2020 was 0.46.13 The U.S. Office of Personnel Management's
General Schedule for government employees can be used for federal government wage rates.14
HHS (2017) points to a study by the Congressional Budget Office (Falk 2012) as a useful source
for estimating benefit values for federal government workers and describes a second source,
OMB Circular A-76 (2003a), as less desirable.
Estimating overhead costs is more challenging, as BLS Occupational Employment Statistics (OES)
and ECEC data do not cover overhead. At EPA, several analyses have used industry-specific
sources such as trade association documents or engineering cost models to obtain estimates of
the categories of costs that fall under "overhead." These costs can usually be converted to a ratio,
as shown by Equation (3):
(3) Overhead cost ratio = Overhead Costs / (Wages + Fringe Benefits)
Then a combined adjustment to wages, that includes both fringe benefits as well as overhead
costs, can be calculated. Analysts should first take care to note whether the overhead ratio is to
be applied to an unloaded wage rate (i.e., without fringe benefits) or to a wage rate already loaded
with fringe benefits, as in Equation (3). Either approach is legitimate, but analysts should be aware
which base is appropriate for the ratio at hand. For example, the U.S. Department of Labor (DOL)
10	For links to datasets, see Table 3.1.
11	A ratio of fringe benefits to total compensation or a ratio of fringe benefits to wages can be calculated from data in Table 1 (national) or
Tables 2 through 4 (by occupation and industry group) of BLS Employer Costs of Employee Compensation (ECEC), available quarterly
at https://www.bls.gov/news.release/ecec.toc.htm. Note that total compensation = wages and salaries + total benefits, and that using
the nomenclature set out in Section 2.1, fringe benefits is equivalent to the BLS term, total benefits; and wages is equivalent to the BLS
term, Wages and salaries. Using Table 4 for manufacturing, fringe benefits were 33.6% of total compensation, and 50.5% of wages.
12	See Table 1 of BLS ECEC June 2020 report: for state and local government workers, fringe benefits were 38.1 % of total compensation,
and 61.5% of wages.
13	For June 2020, Table 1 shows that for civilian workers, on average for the nation, fringe benefits were 31.5% of total compensation, and
46.0% of wages.
14	Available at https://www.opm.gov/policy-data-oversight/pay-leave/salaries-wages/2018/general-schedule/
11

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
(DOL 2016) provides a range of estimates of overhead costs for 16 different occupations. HHS
(2017) converts these costs to ratios assuming a base of wages and fringe benefits.15 These rates
are then only applicable in other analyses that include wages and fringe benefits in the base.
Next, analysts should incorporate the overhead cost ratio into their calculation of the combined
adjustment to employer cost as follows:
•	If the overhead cost ratio includes fringe benefits as in Equation (3), then the combined
adjustment to wages to obtain a fully-loaded wage = (1 + fringe benefit ratio)(1 + overhead cost
ratio). For example, in June 2020 for a national average benefit ratio of 0.46 and assuming an
overhead ratio inclusive of benefits of 0.2, the combined adjustment to wages to obtain the
employer cost of labor = (1,46)(1.2) = 1.75.
•	If the overhead cost ratio excludes fringe benefits (includes only wages), then the combined
adjustment to wages to obtain the employer cost of labor = 1 + fringe benefit ratio + overhead
cost ratio. For example, in June 2020 for a national average benefit ratio of 0.46 and assuming
an overhead cost ratio not inclusive of benefits of 0.3, the combined adjustment to wages to
obtain the employer cost of labor = 1 + 0.46 + 0.3 = 1.76.
For non-work time, to assess the portion of fringe benefits that are voluntary, data in the BLS
ECEC can be adjusted as it separately reports sub-categories of benefits. This allows analysts to
separately identify and remove the value of legally required benefits.
Adjusting for inflation with an appropriate index will be necessary if the data for wages, benefits
or overhead costs is only available for a year that does not correspond to the year of dollar
values used elsewhere in the RIA or ICR. When calculating time costs for work time, since the
perspective is that of the employer, the analyst should use the BLS Employment Cost Index to
adjust the year dollar value.16 To adjust values for non-work time, which is from the perspective of
the individual or household, the analyst should use the BLS Consumer Price Index.
15	See Section 4.2.3 Indirect Cost Data (HHS 2017).
16	"The Employment Cost Index (ECI)... is a quarterly measure of the change in the cost of labor, free from the influence of employment
shifts among occupations and industries. The compensation series includes changes in wages and salaries and employer costs for
employee benefits. The wage and salary series and the benefit costs series provide the change for the two components of compensation.
The ECI is designated as a principal economic indicator. It is the only measure of labor costs that treats wages and salaries and total
compensation consistently, and provides regular sub-series by occupation, industry, and region." BLS (2019b). If analysts expect affected
workers to be located in specific areas of the country, the ECI by area might be useful. These data are available at https://www.bls.gov/
news.release/eci. t13. htm
12

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
If data are not available to estimate industry- or occupation-specific overhead values for the value
of work time,17 this Handbook suggests that EPA analysts should use a default overhead cost
ratio of 20%, or an overhead multiplier of 1.2, applied to a wage rate that is already loaded with
fringe benefits as shown in Equation (3). The 1.2 value is reflective of multiplier values used in prior
EPA RIAs and ICRs that are based on industry- and occupation-specific overhead rates affected
by EPA regulations. These values appear in Appendix A, which provides a summary of program-
specific instruction documents regarding estimating work time values, and of past analyses that
have estimated such values. It offers one example of the value of non-work time. These analyses
were readily accessible and do not reflect a representative sample. Five of the analyses separately
report adjustments for overhead costs; one of those five analyses reports different values for
government entities versus private firms.18 The mean multiplier value used by these five analyses
for overhead costs was 1.23, the median was 1.17 and the range was 1.11 to 1.34.19 Thus, a
value of 1.2 is recommended for use as an EPA default overhead cost multiplier to estimate the
value of work time, but only in those cases when industry- or occupation-specific overhead values
are not available.
3.5 Summary
Table 3.1 summarizes the practical approach outlined in this Handbook for estimating the
value of work and non-work time used to comply with EPA regulations, or for EPA ICRs. A
similar table appears in EPA's forthcoming revised Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analysis.
The characteristics of the regulation or ICR, and the available data, may suggest a different
approach from the one outlined here. In such cases, analysts should explain the reasons for the
alternative approach.
17	In addition to the data sources provided in prior paragraphs of this section, analysts may wish to examine Appendix A for data sources on
overhead costs as well as on wage rates and fringe benefits.
18	EPA remains interested in additional data on relevant overhead rates.
19	This range could be adopted by analysts who are lacking data to estimate industry- or occupation-specific overhead values to conduct a
sensitivity analysis, in addition to or instead of applying the single default value of 1.2.
13

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
Table 3.1 - Estimating Time Costs for EPA Regulatory Impact Analyses and ICRs
Type of Time
Affected
Displaced
Activity
Estimation
Approach
Data
Sources
Work time:
Tasks completed
while working
for pay
Other market
work in the same
industry and
occupation as
workers asked
to complete the
required tasks
Employer costs of
labor = Wages +
Fringe benefits +
Overhead costs
•	BLS OES20 or BLS ECEC data21 on wages and fringe
benefits
•	For overhead costs, can use industry specific data as
available
•	If overhead rates are not available, assume overhead
costs equal 20% of wages plus fringe benefits (i.e., for a
fully-loaded wage rate, multiply benefit-loaded wages by
a factor of "1.2")
Non-work time:
Tasks completed
outside of paid
work time
Other nonmarket
activities such
as leisure and
nonmarket work
Individual valuation
of time = (Wages-
Taxes on earned
income) + Voluntary
benefits
•	BLS OES or BLS ECEC data on wages and voluntary
benefits
•	Adjust wage estimates using CPS data on median
household income before and after taxes to estimate the
average income tax rate22
Note:
For definitions of Wages, Fringe benefits, Overhead, Taxes on earned income and Voluntary benefits, please see Section 2.1.
Acronyms:
•	CPS - Current Population Survey (U.S. Census Bureau); available at http://www.census.gov/cps/data/cpstablecreator.html
•	ECEC - Employer Costs for Employee Compensation (U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics); available at
https://www.bls.gov/news.release/ecec.toc.htm
•	NCS - National Compensation Survey (U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics); available at http://www.bls.gov/ncs/
•	OES - Occupational Employment Statistics (U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics); available at http://www.bls.gov/oes/home.htm
Source: Adapted from Exhibits 2 and 4 HHS (2017): See Appendix C for a description of notable differences.
20	BLS Occupational Employment Statistics (OES): https://www.bls.gov/oes/tables.htm
21	BLS ECEC: BLS's National Compensation Survey has quarterly data on average costs per hour worked: Employer Costs for Employee
Compensation (ECEC), accessible at https://www.bls.gov/web/ecec/ececrse.pdfor https://www.bls.gov/news.release/ecec.toc.htm
22	HHS (2016) gives step-by-step instructions for estimating the median household tax rate with 2014 CPS data on income before and after
taxes. See Appendix B for details.
14

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
4. Considerations and Limitations
Several issues are important to consider when valuing time-use changes due to regulatory
compliance activities and/or ICRs.
4.1 The Potential for Double-Counting
In general, the terminology associated with employer costs of labor lacks clarity in the literature
on valuing time use. For example, terms such as "indirect," "overhead" and "loaded" are used
inconsistently across sources to represent a variety of cost categories. Depending on which
cost categories they represent, there may be duplication or partial overlap with cost categories
included separately and directly (i.e., not attached to labor hours) within an analysis of regulatory
costs. Or there may be duplication of cost categories between overhead and those included
as fringe benefits. Analysts should be careful to avoid double-counting, whenever possible.
Text Box 4.1 offers two examples to illustrate the variation in the use of terminology as well as the
potential for double-counting.
Text Box 4.1 - Examples of Potential Double-Counting
Example 1: Labor overhead cost categories potentially overlapping with
directly measured costs
The Regulatory Impact Analysis for EPA's Final Regulations for the Management of Hazardous Waste
Pharmaceuticals (EPA 2018) carefully considers how overhead cost categories might overlap with directly
measured costs. BLS NCS data is used to estimate hourly wages for the various professional and clerical
positions required to undertake (or be released from) compliance activities. BLS ECEC data is then used
to account for fringe benefits by adjusting the hourly wage rates by an average ratio for the affected
industry groups. Since industry specific data on overhead costs was not available, a final adjustment
is made for overhead costs based on an engineering model for estimating remedial action costs. The
engineering model includes a set of cost categories within overhead that is not entirely clear, causing a
concern that they might overlap with direct cost categories that are not attached to labor. The RIA carefully
considers the components of cost categories that the engineering model includes and compares them to
the overhead cost categories that the RIA directly estimates. The comparison illustrates that they do not
coincide or overlap.23
23 See pp. 53-54 and footnote 49 of the "Regulatory Impact Analysis for EPA's Final Regulations for the Management of Hazardous Waste
Pharmaceuticals" (EPA 2018).
15

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
Example 2: Labor overhead cost categories potentially overlapping with fringe benefits
To illustrate potential overlap between overhead cost categories and fringe benefits consider EPA's Air
Pollution Cost Manual (EPA 2017). It describes overhead for pollution abatement activities as falling into
two broad categories: payroll overhead and plant overhead. It defines payroll overhead as direct labor
expenses including Social Security contributions, group insurance and other fringe benefits.24 In this case,
if fringe benefits were first added to the wage rate, it would be incorrect to also add "payroll overhead," to
estimate the value of work time.
EPA's 2016 Regional Haze ICR renewal, an entry in Appendix A, successfully avoids double-counting by
separately including benefits and overhead without overlap. It includes benefits (26% of the wage rate)
and overhead (29% of the wage rate) for a total of 55% of the wage rate. This is consistent with EPA's
Air Pollution Cost Manual (2017), also in Appendix A, in that labor costs range between 1.5 and 1.7
times the wage.
4.2 Transfer Payments as Proxy for Social Costs
In benefit-cost analysis, payments, such as Social Security taxes and unemployment insurance,
are normally excluded from social costs because they are transfer payments. Monetary transfers
between groups do not reflect the use of real resources (OMB 2003, EPA 2014). However, they
are part of the employer's expense for a unit of workforce time which serves as a proxy for the
opportunity cost of work time. This is because the firm chooses its labor demand at the point
where its marginal cost of labor equals the social (consumer) value of production generated
by an additional hour of labor. Therefore, when estimating the value of work time in regulatory
compliance activities, analysts should include the costs of these payments to determine the value
of time as viewed from the employer's perspective. This does not change the conclusion reached
elsewhere that transfer payments should be excluded from social costs.
4.3 Quasi-fixed Cost Models
This Handbook relies on relatively simple models of behavior to generate its conclusions. Quasi-
fixed cost models are one way to consider costs that do not vary by hours worked. In these
models, analysts can distinguish between employer costs that vary by hours worked such as
wages and employer-paid taxes and some components of fringe benefits (e.g., overtime pay), and
those that do not. The latter are costs that vary not by hours worked but instead by the number
of workers. These quasi-fixed costs could include overhead costs such as office space or some
components of fringe benefits such as employer-provided health insurance (Ehrenberg and Smith
2012). When analyzing regulatory requirements under the assumption of quasi-fixed costs, an
analyst must explicitly model the employer's choice between an additional hour worked by the
current labor force or by an additional hire.
24 See p. 34 (EPA 2017).
16

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
According to quasi-fixed cost models, the value of the marginal product will depend on the choice
Petween the numPer of workers and the numPer of hours. If there is only a change in hours
worked, the hourly wage + fringe Penefits + overhead approach, or Equation (1), may not serve
as a good proxy for the opportunity cost of time-use. For example, many ICRs assume that few
hours are needed to complete the information request, so firms are less likely to hire new workers
than in cases that require high amounts of time to comply with regulatory requirements or respond
to an ICR. In principle, quasi-fixed costs, such as overhead, would need to be removed from the
proxy value, but NCEE has not yet identified how to implement this approach with existing data.
4.4 Opportunity Cost of Non-work Time
The opportunity cost of non-work time is highly uncertain as this is time spent outside the formal
labor market with no observable market price. Application of the labor-leisure trade-off rests on
the assumption that the individual can freely choose their work hours at the going wage rate.
Most workers in the U.S., however, cannot. If an individual is working more than they would prefer
to, their opportunity cost of time will be greater than their wage rate, and vice versa.
The labor-leisure trade-off suggests that even individuals who are unemployed or not participating
in the labor market value their time at the rate of foregone earnings. Information about which
industry or occupational wages are relevant to such individuals can be sparse. The advice in the
current document is to apply a national average wage, resolving the issue with a very broad stroke
and likely representing the opportunity cost of such individuals with significant error.
Recent empirical research has found that the value of non-work time varies substantially
across individuals and is not well represented by a multiple (or ratio) of their implied wage rate
(Lloyd-Smith, et al. 2019). Analysts should remain aware of the uncertainties associated with
representing the opportunity cost of non-work time as foregone earnings.
17

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
Appendix A
Approaches to Time Cost Estimation in Past EPA Documents
This appendix presents information drawn from a convenience sample of 11 EPA documents
that estimated, or outlined an approach to estimating, the value of time costs. The EPA office
that generated each document, the document title, its approach to valuing work time and non-
work time (if applicable), and its total wage adjustment factor are identified below. Some of the
documents are directed at valuing work time at private firms, others at government agencies.
18

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
(1)
EPA Office:
Office of Environmental Information (OEI) Collection Strategies Division
Document Title
"ICR Handbook: EPA's Guide to Writing Information Collection Requests
under the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995" (U.S. EPA 2009).25
Approach for estimating the value of work time
For private firms, and for state and local government: Wages + Benefits + Overhead26
Wages: Use BLS data, with a gradation that reflects occupation. Uses industry-
specific when possiPle.
Fringe Benefits: Uses BLS ECEC.
Overhead: Consult the original ICR, or corresponding economic analysis, or conduct
consultations specific to regulated industry.
For EPA burden costs: Wages x 1.6
Wages: Use OPM General Schedule rates.27
Fringe Benefits: Apply the standard government Penefits multiplication factor of 0.6 x Wage.
Approach for estimating the value of non-work time
N/A
Total wage adjustment
The adjustment factor will vary Py ICR.
No default value offered.
25	U.S. EPA (2009). "ICR Handbook: EPA's Guide to Writing Information Collection Requests Under the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995."
Revised 10/2009. Office of Environmental Information. https://www.regulations.gov/contentStreamer?documentld=EPA-HQ-OPPT-
2016-0426-0090&contentType=pdf. In Docket for "TSCA Inventory Notification (Active/Inactive) Requirements"; Docket ID: EPA-HQ-
OPPT-2016-0426. Agency: Environmental Protection Agency (EPA); https://www.regulations.gov/docket?D=EPA-HQ-OPPT-2016-0426.
Final rule 8/11/2017.
26	U.S. EPA (2009). See Section 6(b)(i) Estimating Labor Costs.
27	U.S. EPA(2009).Seep.A-31.
19

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
(2)
EPA Office:
Office of Emergency Management
Document Title
"Regulatory Impact Analysis: Accidental Release Prevention Requirements:
Risk Management Programs Under the Clean Air Act." Section 112(r)(7)
(U.S. EPA 2016).28
Approach for estimating the value of work time
For private firms, and for state and local government: Wage rate x 1.5
Wages: Uses BLS OES.
Fringe Benefits: The multiplier of 0.5 is based on an average for the sectors affected, as
estimated by BLS ECEC.
Overhead: None Added.
Approach for estimating the value of non-work time
N/A
Total wage adjustment
1.5
28 U.S. EPA (2016). "Regulatory Impact Analysis: Accidental Release Prevention Requirements: Risk Management Programs Under the Clean
Air Act." Section 112(r)(7). December 16, 2016. https://www.regulations.gov/document?D=EPA-HQ-OEM-2015-0725-0734
20

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
(3)
EPA Office:
Office of Resource Conservation and Recovery
Document Title
"Regulatory Impact Analysis for EPA's Final Regulations for the Management
of Hazardous Waste Pharmaceuticals." (U.S. EPA 2018).29
Approach for estimating the value of work time
For private firms: {Wage rate x (1.4)} x (1.336)
Wages: Uses BLS NCS.
Fringe Benefits: Uses BLS ECEC average fringe benefits multiplier for health
service professionals.
Overhead: Remedial Action Cost Engineering Requirements (RACER) cost
estimating software.30
Approach for estimating the value of non-work time
N/A
Total wage adjustment
1.9
29	U.S. EPA (2018). "Regulatory Impact Analysis for EPA's Final Regulations for the Management of Hazardous Waste Pharmaceuticals."
October 2018. https://www.regulations.gov/document?D=EPA-HQ-RCRA-2007-0932-0412
30	RACER overhead includes fixed overhead, insurance and profit.
21

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
(4)
EPA Office:
Office of Pollution Prevention and Toxics
Document Title
"Wage Rates for Economic Analyses of the Toxics Release Inventory
Program." (Rice 2002).31
Approach for estimating the value of work time
For private firms: Wage rate x (1+ 0.40 + 0.17)
Wage: Uses BLS ECEC data, by labor category (managerial, technical, clerical).
Fringe Benefits: Uses BLS ECEC, by labor category (managerial, technical, clerical).
Overhead: Uses information provided by the chemical industry and chemical industry trade
associations; specifically:
Heiden Associates (1989). "Final Report: A Study of Industry Compliance Costs Under
the Final Comprehensive Assessment Information Rule." Prepared for the Chemical
Manufacturers Association. December 14, 1989.
Approach for estimating the value of non-work time
N/A
Total wage adjustment
1.57
31 Rice, C. (2002). "Wage Rates for Economic Analyses of the Toxics Release Inventory Program." Analytical Support Branch, Environmental
Analysis Division, Office of Environmental Information, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, https://www.regulations.gov/
document?D=EPA-HQ-OPPT-2016-0231-0122
22

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
(5)
EPA Office:
Office of Pesticides Programs
Document Title
"Economic Analysis of Final Amendments to 40 CFR Part 171: Certification
of Pesticide Applicators." (U.S. EPA 2016c).32
Approach for estimating the value of work time
For private firms: Wage rate x (1 + 0.46)
Wage: For adults, uses BLS OES (national industry-specific occupational wage estimates).
For 16- and 17-year-olds, uses 0.75 x {Wage rate x (1 + 0.46)} for commercial pesticide
applicators; or 0.60 x {Wage rate x (1 + 0.46)} for private pesticide applicators.
For under age 16, uses 0.50 x {Wage rate x (1 + 0.46)} for private pesticide applicators.
Fringe Benefits: Uses BLS ECEC.
Overhead: None Added
Approach for estimating the value of non-work time
N/A
Total wage adjustment
1.46
32 U.S. EPA (2016c). "Economic Analysis of Final Amendments to 40 CFR Part 171: Certification of Pesticide Applicators." https://www.
regulations.gov/document?D=EPA-HQ-OPP-2011-0183-0807(accessed on December 7,2019).
23

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
(6)
EPA Office:
Office of Pollution Prevention and Toxics
Document Title
"Final Rule - Economic Analysis of Regulation of Methylene Chloride, Paint
and Coating Remover" under TSCA Section 6(a) (U.S. EPA 2019).33
Approach for estimating the value of work time
For private firms: Wage rate x (1 + 0.54 + 0.17)
Wage: Uses BLS OES.
Fringe Benefits: Uses BLS ECEC.
Overhead: An overhead rate of 17% is used based on assumptions in two EPA documents:
Wage Rates for Economic Analysis of the Toxics Release Inventory Program (Rice 2002)
and the Revised Economic Analysis for the Amended Inventory Update Rule: Final
Report (EPA 2002).
Approach for estimating the value of non-work time
For consumers: Wage rate x (1 - 0.302)
Wage: Uses BLS CPS to calculate median U.S. hourly wage.
Tax rate: Uses the Tax Foundation's national tax rate of 30.2%.
Total wage adjustment
1.71 for value of work time
0.698 for value of non-work time
33 U.S. EPA (2019). "Final Rule - Economic Analysis of Regulation of Methylene Chloride, Paint and Coating Remover." TSCA Section 6(a)
(EPA Docket EPA-HQ-OPPT-2016-0231; RIN 2070-AK07). https://www.regulations.gov/document?D=EPA-HQ-OPPT-2016-0231-0990
24

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
(7)
EPA Office:
Office of Air and Radiation
Document Title
"Information Collection Request Supporting Statement for EPA ICR
Number 1813.09, Renewal of the ICR for the Regional Haze Regulations."
(U.S. EPA 2016a).34
Approach for estimating the value of work time
For state agencies: Wage rate x (1 + 0.26 + 0.29)
Wage: Uses 2015 OPM federal government pay schedule wage rates.
Fringe Benefits: Cites 2006 draft ICR which uses "Benefits (at 16%)" and "Sick leave/
Vacation (at 10%)," consistent with methods for previous New Source Review ICRs.35
Overhead: Cites 2006 draft ICR which gives a dollar value of "General Overhead" that is 29%
of unloaded wages, consistent with methods for previous New Source Review ICRs.
Approach for estimating the value of non-work time
N/A
Total wage adjustment
1.55
34	U.S. EPA (2016a). "Information Collection Request Supporting Statement for EPA ICR Number 1813.09, Renewal of the ICR for the
Regional Haze Regulations." https://www.regulations.gov/document?D=EPA-HQ-OAR-2003-0162-0017
35	U.S. EPA (2006). "Information Collection Request for Changes to Prevention of Significant Deterioration and Nonattainment New
Source Review: Emissions Test for Electric Generating Units." August 2006: p. 20. https://www.regulations.gov/document?D=EPA-HQ-
OAR-2005-0163-0355
However, U.S. EPA (2006) provides a source for benefits and overhead values that is U.S. EPA (2002a). "EPA Air Pollution Control Cost
Manual," 6th ed. https://www3.epa.gov/ttn/ecas/docs/c_allchs.pdf
25

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
(8)
EPA Office:
Office of Air and Radiation
Document Title
"Regulatory Impact Analysis for the Proposed Emission Guidelines for
Greenhouse Gas Emissions from Existing Electric Utility Generating Units;
Revisions to Emission Guideline Implementing Regulations; Revisions to
New Source Review Program." (U.S. EPA 2018a).36
Approach for estimating the value of work time
For federal, state and local government: Wage rate x (1 + 0.26 + 0.32)
Wage: Uses OPM federal government staff salaries. (Cites "Renewal of the ICR for the
Regional Haze Rule." [U.S. EPA 2002b]).37
Fringe Benefits: "Benefits at 16% of the direct salary cost," "Sick and annual leave at
10% of direct salary cost" from "Renewal of the ICR for the Regional Haze Rule." (U.S.
EPA 2002b, p 21).
Overhead: "General overhead at 32% of direct salary cost" from "Renewal of the ICR for the
Regional Haze Rule." (U.S. EPA 2002b, 21).
For private firms: Benefits loaded wage rate x (1 + 0.32)
Wage: BLS ECEC
Fringe Benefits: Uses BLS ECEC
Overhead: Uses the "operating permits methodology" which results in 32% of total
compensation (U.S. EPA 2002b, 23).
Approach for estimating the value of non-work time
N/A
Total wage adjustment
1.58 for value of government time.
36	U.S. EPA (2018a). "Regulatory Impact Analysis for the Proposed Emission Guidelines for Greenhouse Gas Emissions from Existing Electric
Utility Generating Units; Revisions to Emission Guideline Implementing Regulations; Revisions to New Source Review Program." p. 3-12.
https://www. epa.gov/sites/production/files/2018-08/documents/utilities_ria_proposed_ace_2018-08.pdf
37	U.S. EPA (2002b). "Information Collection Request Supporting Statement for EPA ICR Number 1813.04, Renewal of the ICR for the
Regional Haze Rule." November 2002. https://www.regulations.gov/document?D=EPA-HQ-OAR-2003-0162-0001
26

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
(9)
EPA Office:
Office of Air and Radiation
Document Title
EPA Air Pollution Control Cost manual, Chapter 2 "Cost Estimation:
Concepts and Methodology" (U.S. EPA 2017)38
Approach for estimating the value of work time
For private firms: Wage rate x (1 + 0.5 through 0.7)
Wage: Uses BLS "Monthly Labor Review" and other publications.
Fringe Benefits: "Payroll overhead includes expenses directly associated with ... labor, such
as: workmen's compensation, Social Security and pension fund contributions, vacations,
group insurance, and other fringe benefits." US EPA 2017 p. 35.
Overhead: "...plant (or 'factory') overhead accounts for expenses ... including: plant
protection, control laboratories, employee amenities, plant lighting, parking areas, and
landscaping." Estimate from Peters, M.S. and Timmerhaus, K.D., Plant Design and Economics
for Chemical Engineers (Fifth Edition), McGraw-Hill, New York, 2002.
Approach for estimating the value of non-work time
N/A
Total wage adjustment
1.5 to 1.7
OAR Cost Manual uses the average: 1.6.
38 U.S. EPA (2017). "EPA Air Pollution Control Cost Manual." https://www.epa.gov/economic-and-cost-anatysis-air-pottution-regutations/
cost-reports-and-guidance-air-poitution; Chapter 2, "Cost Estimation: Concepts and Methodology." https://www.epa.gov/sites/
production/fites/2017- 12/documents/epaccmcostestimationmethodchapter_7thedition_2017.pdf
27

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
(10)
EPA Office:
Office of Ground Water and Drinking Water
Document Title
"Office of Groundwater and Drinking Water Labor Costs for National Drinking
Water Rules." Science Applications International Corporation. (2011).39
Approach for estimating the value of work time
For private and public water systems, Wage rate x (1 + 0.4)
Wage: Uses the Community Water System Survey (CWSS)40
Fringe Benefits: BLS and CWSS
Overhead: Not separately reported.41
Approach for estimating the value of non-work time
N/A
Total wage adjustment
1.4
39	Science Applications International Corporation (2011). "Labor Costs for National Drinking Water Rules." https://www.regulations.gov/
document?D=EPA-HQ-OW-2017-0300-0758
40	Wages vary by occupation and system size.
41	Overhead is included elsewhere and omitted from labor costs to avoid double-counting.
28

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
(11)
EPA Office:
Office of Water
Document Title
"Technical and Economic Development Document for the Final
Effluent Limitations Guidelines and Standards for the Dental Category."
(U.S. EPA 2016b).42
Approach ONE for estimating the value of work time
For dental assistants: (Wage rate x 1)
Wages: Uses BLS OES.43
Fringe Benefits: Not included
Overhead: Not included
Approach TWO for estimating the value of work time
For maintenance costs: Service call labor rates
Wages: Uses vendor cost estimates for hourly service call cost estimates.44
Fringe Benefits: Not specified
Overhead: Not specified
Approach for estimating the value of non-work time
N/A
Total wage adjustment
1 or Not specified
42	U.S. EPA (2016b). "Final Supporting Data for the Costing Analysis." Memorandum to the Public Record for the Dental Category Final
Rule. Office of Water. Washington, DC. December. DCN DA00471.
43	BLS Occupational Employment and Wage data for Dental Assistants.
44	See p. A-2 in U.S. EPA (2016b).
29

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
Appendix B
HHS (2016) gives step-by-step instructions for estimating the median household tax rate with
2014 CPS data on income before and after taxes:
To estimate the tax rate, including both federal and state taxes, analysts should use
data on household income before and after taxes collected in the CPS, a joint effort by
the U.S. Census Bureau (Census) and BLS. The CPS collects data from a nationally
representative sample of 60,000 households on a monthly basis. The Census maintains a
tool called the "CPS Table Creator," which allows analysts to create customized data tables
(HHS 2016, p.31).
To estimate mean or median household income before taxes, under "Data Options" select
the relevant calendar year and get a count of "Persons-All." Next, "Define Your Table" by
selecting "Household Income - Alternative" as a row variable. Under the "Statistics" section,
in the subsection called "Additional numeric variable statistics" choose "Household Income-
Alternative" and "Mean" or "Median." In the "Income Definition" section, select "Customize
your own income definition" and then select "1. Earnings (wages, salaries, and self-
employment income)" and "19. Federal Earned Income Credit." For household income after
taxes, follow the same steps and add the following additional selections in the customized
income definition: "20. Federal Income Taxes after refundable credits except EIC," "21. State
income taxes after all refundable credits," and "22. Payroll taxes (FICA and other mandatory
deductions)." For 2014 (select 2015 as the most recent year of data), median pre-tax
household income ($53,000) minus post-tax income ($44,599) and divided by median pretax
income results in a median tax rate of 16 percent. (To access the CPS Table Creator, see
http://www.census.gov/cps/data/cpstablecreator.html). (HHS 2016, p. 31n73).
30

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
Appendix C
There are many differences between Table 3.1 and Exhibits 2 and 4 in HHS (2017), however two
differences are notable:
Whereas HHS recommended a multiplier of "2" for obtaining a fully loaded wage rate in
the absence of industry- or occupation-specific data on fringe benefits and overhead, EPA
recommends that analysts obtain an estimate for industry specific fringe benefits from BLS ECEC.
When a nationwide estimate is needed, the national average ratio of fringe benefits to wages
reported by BLS's ECEC (currently 0.46) can be used. When industry- or occupation-specific
overhead values are unavailable, EPA recommends a multiplier of "1.2" to be applied to wage
rates already loaded with fringe benefits (as shown in Equation [3]) for EPA regulatory analyses
and ICR burden estimates.
Whereas HHS recommended estimating the value of non-work time as "post tax wages," EPA
recommends adding in voluntary benefits.
31

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
References
Amoako-Tuffour, J. and R. Martinez-Espineira. 2012. "Leisure and the Net Opportunity Cost of Travel Time in
Recreation Demand Analysis: An Application to Gros Morne National Park." Journal of Applied Economics 15: 25-49.
Ehrenberg, R.and R. Smith. 2012. Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy 11. Boston, MA. Prentice Hall.
http://fac.ksu.edu.sa/sites/defauli/files/Modern_labor_economics_theory_and_public_policy_0.pdf
Falk, J. 2012. "Comparing Benefits and Total Compensation in the Federal Government and the Private
Sector." Congressional Budget Office Working Paper Series. https://www.cbo.gOv/sites/default/files/112th-
congress-2011 -2012/workingpaper/2012-04fedbenefitswp0.pdf
Feldstein, M. 1978. "The Private and Social Costs of Unemployment." The American Economic Review.
68(2): 155-158.
Fezzi, C., I. Bateman, and S. Ferrini. 2014. "Using revealed preferences to estimate the Value of Travel Time to
recreation sites." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 67(1): 58-70.
https://doi.Org/10.1016/j.jeem.2013.10.003.
Gonzalez, R.M. 1997. "The Value of Time: A Theoretical Review." Transport Reviews 17,3:245-266. DOI:
10.1080/01441649708716984
Heagney, E.C., M. Rose, A. Ardeshiri, and M. Kovac. 2019. "The Economic Value of Tourism and Recreation Across a
Large Protected Area Network." Land Use Policy 88.
Heiden Associates. 1989. "Final Report: A Study of Industry Compliance Costs Under the Final Comprehensive
Assessment Information Rule." Prepared for the Chemical Manufacturers Association. December 14,1989.
Jara-Diaz, S. and J. Rosales-Salas. 2017. "Beyond Transport Time: A Review of Time Use Modeling." Transportation
Research Part A: Policy and Practice 97:209-230. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tra.2017.01.022.
Lakdawalla, D.N., J.A. Doshi, L.P. Garrison Jr., C.E. Phelps, A. Basu, and P.M. Danzon. 2018. "Defining Elements
of Value in Health Care -A Health Economics Approach: An ISPOR Special Task Force Report." Value in
Health 2] \ 131-139.
Lloyd-Smith, P., J.K. Abbott, W. Adamowicz, and D. Willard. 2019. "Decoupling the Value of Leisure Time
from Labor Market Returns in Travel Cost Models." Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource
Economists 6(2): 215-42.
Manns, L. 2015. "Buyers and Sellers Share the Burden of Taxes In the New Equilibrium Buyers Pay." Course
H e ro. www. course hero. com/file/p2ctbp8/Buyers-and-sellers-share-the-burden-of- taxes-ln-the-ne w-
equilibrium -buyers-pay/
32

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
Meisenheimer II, J.R. 2005. "Real Compensation, 1979 to 2003: Analysis from Several Data Sources." Monthly Labor
Review. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, https://www.bls.gov/opub/mlr/2005/05/art1full.pdf
Peters, M.S., K.D. Timmerhaus, and R.E. West. 2002. "Plant Design and Economics for Chemical Engineers."
5. McGraw-Hill.
Phaneuf, D.J. and T. Requate. 2016. "A Course in Environmental Economics: Theory, Policy, and Practice." Cambridge
University Press.
Rice, C. 2002. "Wage Rates for Economic Analysis of The Toxic's Release Inventory Program." Office of Environmental
Information: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (Ed.).
https://www.regulations.gov/document?D=EPA-HQ-0PPT-2016-0231-0122
Science Applications International Corporation. 2011. "Labor Costs for National Drinking Water Rules." Contractor
Report to the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Office of Groundwater and Drinking Water.
https://www.regulations.gov/document?D=EPA-HQ-0W-2017-0300-0758
Small, K.A. 2012. "Valuation of Travel Time." Economics of Transportation 1: 2-14.
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2019. "National Compensation Measures: Handbook of Methods".
https://www. bis. go v/opub/hom/ncs/pdf/ncs.pdf
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2019a. "BLS Information.": Glossary, https://www.bls.gov/bls/glossary.htm
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2019b. "How to Use the Employment Cost Index for Escalation."
https://www. bis. go v/ncs/ect/escalator. htm
U.S. Department of Health and Human Services. 2016. Guidelines for Regulatory Impact Analysis. Office of the
Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation.
https://aspe.hhs.gov/system/files/pdf/242926/HHS_RIAGuidance.pdf
U.S. Department of Health and Human Services. 2017. "Valuing Time in U.S. Department of Health and Human
Services Regulatory Impact Analyses: Conceptual Framework and Best Practices." Final Report.
https://aspe. hhs.go v/system/files/pdf/257746/V0 T.pdf
U.S. Department of Labor. 2016. "Labor Cost Inputs Used in the Employee Benefits Security Administration, Office of
Policy and Research's Regulatory Impacts Analyses and Paperwork Reduction Act Burden Calculations"
https://www.dol.gov/sites/default/files/ebsa/laws-and-regulations/rules-and-regulations/technical-appendices/
labor-cost-inputs-used-in-ebsa-opr-ria-and-pra-burden-calculations-august-2016.pdf
U.S. Department of Transportation. 2016. Revised Departmental Guidance on Valuation of Travel Time in Economic
Analysis. Memorandum to Secretarial Officers, Modal Administrators, https://www.transportation.gov/sites/dot.gov/
files/docs/2016%20Revised%20Value%20of%20Travel%20Time%20Guidance.pdf
33

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 2002. Revised Economic Analysis for the Amended Inventory Update
Rule: Final Report. Office of Pollution Prevention and Toxics, Economic and Policy Analysis Branch. (EPA-HQ-
OPPT-2002-0054-0260).
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 2002a. EPA Air Pollution Control Cost Manual 6. EPA/452/B-02-001.
https://www3.epa.gov/ttn/ecas/docs/c_allchs.pdf
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 2002b. Information Collection Request Supporting Statement for EPA ICR
Number 1813.04, Renewal of the ICR for the Regional Haze Rule.
https://www.regulations.gov/document?D=EPA-HQ-0AR-2003-0162-0001
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 2005. Valuing Time Losses Due to Illness: Under the 1996Amendments to the
Safe Drinking Water Act. Office of Water. EPA 815-R-05-003. https://nepis.epa.gov/Exe/ZyNET.exe/P100VCA8.TXT7Z
yActionD=ZyDocument&Client=EPA&lndex=2000+Thru+2005&Docs=&Query=&Time=&EndTime=&SearchMeth
od= 1 & TocRestrict=n& Toc=& TocEntry=&QField=&QFieldYear=&QFieldMonth=&QFieldDay=&lntQFieldOp=0&ExtQ
Field0p=0&XmlQuery=&File=D%3A%5Czyfiles%5Clndex%20Data%5C00thru05%5CTxt%5C00000038%5CP100
VCA8.txt&User=AN0NYM0US&Password=anonymous&SortMethod=h%7C-&MaximumDocuments=1&FuzzyDegr
ee=0&lmageQuality=r75g8/r75g8/x150y150g 16/i425&Display=hpfr&DefSeekPage=x&SearchBack=ZyActionL&B
ack=ZyActionS&BackDesc=Results%20page&MaximumPages= 1 &ZyEntry= 1 &SeekPage=x&ZyPURL#
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 2006. Information Collection Request for Changes to Prevention of Significant
Deterioration and Nonattainment New Source Review: Emissions Test for Electric Generating Units. August.
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 2009. ICR Handbook: EPA's Guide to Writing Information Collection Requests
Under the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995. Revised Oct. 2009. Office of Environmental Information, Collection
Strategies Division.
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 2014. Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses. Updated May 2014.
National Center for Environmental Economics, Office of Policy. Dec. 17, 2010.
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 2016. Regulatory Impact Analysis, Accidental Release Prevention Requirements:
Risk Management Programs Under the Clean Air Act, Section 112(r)(7).
https://www. regulations.gov/document?D=EPA-HQ-0EM-2015-0725-0734
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 2016a. Information Collection Request Supporting Statement for EPA ICR
Number 1813.09, Renewal of the ICR for the Regional Haze Regulations.
https://www.regulations.gov/document?D=EPA-HQ-0AR-2003-0162-0017
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 2016b. Final Supporting Data for the Costing Analysis. Memorandum to the
Public Record for the Dental Category Final Rule. Office of Water. Washington, DC. DCN DA00471.
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 2016c. Economic Analysis of Final Amendments to 40 CFR Part 171:
Certification of Pesticide Applicators. https://www.regulations.gov/document?D=EPA-HQ-0PP-2011-0183-0807
34

-------
Handbook on Valuing Changes in Time Use Induced by Regulatory Requirements and Other EPA Actions
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 2017. EPA Air Pollution Control Cost Manual, Chapter 2 "Cost
Estimation: Costs and Methodology." https://www.epa.gov/sites/production/files/2017-12/documents/
epaccmcostestimationmethodchapter_7thedition_2017.pdf
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 2018. Regulatory Impact Analysis for EPA's Final Regulations for the
Management of Hazardous Waste Pharmaceuticals.
https://www.reguiations.gov/document?D=EPA-HQ-RCRA-2007-0932-0412
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 2018a. Regulatory Impact Analysis for the Proposed Emission Guidelines
for Greenhouse Gas Emissions from Existing Electric Utility Generating Units; Revisions to Emission Guideline
Implementing Regulations; Revisions to New Source Review Program.
https://www.epa.gov/sites/production/fiies/2018-08/documents/utilities_ria_proposed_ace_2018-08.pdf
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 2019. Final Rule - Economic Analysis of Regulation of Methylene Chloride, Paint
and Coating Remover. TSCA Section 6(a) (EPA Docket EPA-HQ-OPPT-2016-0231; RIN 2070-AK07).
https://www.reguiations.gov/document?D=EPA-HQ-0PPT-2016-0231 -0990
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, forthcoming. Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analysis. National Center for
Environmental Economics, Office of Policy.
U.S. Government Accountability Office. 2018. "Paperwork Reduction Act: Agencies Could Better Leverage Review
Processes and Public Outreach to Improve Burden Estimates." https://www.gao.gov/assets/700/693057.pdf
U.S. Office of Management and Budget. 2003. Circular A-4, Regulatory Analysis. September 17.
https://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/whitehouse.gov/fiies/omb/circulars/A4/a-4.pdfAccesse6 October 15, 2018.
U.S. Office of Management and Budget. 2003a. Circular A-76 (Revised), Performance of Commercial Activities. May
29. https://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/whitehouse.gov/fiies/omb/circulars/A76/a76_incl_tech_correction.pdf
U.S. Office of Management and Budget. 2011. Regulatory Impact Analysis: Frequently Asked Questions (FAQs).
https://obamawhitehouse.archives.gov/sites/default/fiies/omb/assets/0MB/circulars/a004/a-4_FAQ.pdf
Wolff, H. 2014. "Value of time: Speeding behavior and gasoline prices." Journal of Environmental Economics and
Management. 67(1): 71-88. https://doi.Org/10.1016/j.jeem.2013.11.002
35

-------