/ O \

\ '

PRO"^

Regulatory Impact Analysis for the Proposed
National Emission Standards for Hazardous Air
Pollutants: Gasoline Distribution Technology
Review and Standards of Performance for Bulk
Gasoline Terminals Review


-------
ii


-------
EPA-452/R-22-002
June 2022

Regulatory Impact Analysis for the Proposed National Emission Standards for Hazardous Air Pollutants: Gasoline
Distribution Technology Review and Standards of Performance for Bulk Gasoline Terminals Review

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency
Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards
Health and Environmental Impacts Division
Research Triangle Park, NC

ill


-------
CONTACT INFORMATION

This document has been prepared by staff from the Office of Air and Radiation, U.S.
Environmental Protection Agency. Questions related to this document should be addressed to the
Air Economics Group in the Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards, U.S. Environmental
Protection Agency, Office of Air and Radiation, Research Triangle Park, North Carolina 27711
(email: OAQPSeconomics@epa.gov).

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

We acknowledge the help of the Research Triangle Institute in preparing the compliance cost and
emission reductions for the regulatory options analyzed in this RIA.

iv


-------
TABLE OF CONTENTS

Table of Contents	v

List of Tables	viii

List of Figures	xi

1	Executive Summary	1-1

1.1	Background	1-1

1.1.1	NESHAP subparts R and BBBBBB	1-1

1.1.2	NSPS subpart XX	1-3

1.2	Market Failure	1-5

1.3	Results for Proposed Action	1-5

1.3.1	Baseline for the Regulation	1-5

1.3.2	GACT6B	1-6

1.3.2.1	Options Examined in this RIA	1-6

1.3.2.2	Overview of Costs and Benefits for the Proposed Options	1-7

1.3.3	MACTR	1-9

1.3.3.1	Options Examined in this RI A	1-9

1.3.3.2	Overview of Costs and Benefits for the Proposed Options	1-9

1.3.4	NSPS XX	1-11

1.3.4.1	Options Examined in this RI A	1-11

1.3.4.2	Overview of Costs and Benefits for the Proposed Options	1-11

1.3.5	All Rules	1-13

1.3.5.1 Overview of Costs and Benefits for All Rules Cumulatively	1-13

1.4	Organization of this Report	1-14

2	Industry Profile	2-1

2.1	Introduction	2-1

2.2	Supply Side	2-1

2.2.1	The Gasoline Distribution Network	2-1

2.2.2	Downstream Marketing Arrangements for Refined Petroleum Products	2-5

2.2.3	Industry Organization	2-7

2.2.3.1	Concentration and Vertical Integration	2-7

2.2.3.2	Entry Barriers	2-9

2.2.3.3	Employment	2-10

2.3	Demand Side	2-11

2.3.1 Factors that Influence Gasoline Consumption	2-13

2.4	Market Conditions	2-15

2.4.1	Consumption	2-15

2.4.2	Prices	2-16

2.4.3	Trends and Projections	2-19

3	Emissions and Engineering Costs Analysis	3-1

3.1	Introduction	3-1

3.2	Emissions Points, Controls, and Model Plants	3-1

3.2.1.1	Bulk Gasoline Terminals	3-2

3.2.1.2	Bulk Gasoline Plants	3-2

3.2.1.3	Pipeline Breakout Stations	3-2

3.2.1.4	Pipeline Pumping Stations	3-2

3.2.2 Emission Points at Regulated Facilities	3-3

3.2.2.1	Loading Racks	3-3

3.2.2.2	Storage Tanks	3-4

3.2.2.3	Equipment Leaks	3-5

v


-------
3.2.2.4 Cargo Tanks	3-6

3.2.3	Model Plants	3-8

3.2.3.1	Loading Racks	3-8

3.2.3.2	Storage Tanks	3-9

3.2.3.3	Cargo Tanks	3-10

3.2.3.4	Pipeline Pumping Stations	3-10

3.2.3.5	Pipeline Breakout Stations	3-11

3.2.3.6	Bulk Gasoline Plants	3-11

3.2.3.7	Bulk Gasoline Terminals	3-12

3.2.4	Activity Data	3-13

3.2.5	Baseline	3-14

3.2.6	Product Recovery	3-15

3.3	Description of Regulatory Options	3-17

3.3.1	GACT6B	3-17

3.3.2	MACTR	3-20

3.3.3	NSPSXXa	3-22

3.4	Emissions Reduction Analysis	3-23

3.4.1	Baseline VOC/HAP Emissions Estimates	3-23

3.4.2	Projected VOC/HAP Emissions Reduction	3-24

3.4.3	Projected Secondary Emissions Increases	3-26

3.5	Engineering Cost Analysis	3-28

3.5.1	Detailed Impacts Tables	3-28

3.5.1.1	GACT6B	3-28

3.5.1.2	MACTR	3-31

3.5.1.3	NSPSXXa	3-32

3.5.2	Summary Cost Tables	3-34

4	Human Health Benefits of Emissions Reductions	4-1

4.1	Introduction	4-1

4.2	VOC-RELATED HUMAN HEALTH BENEFITS	4-1

4.2.1	Estimating Ozone Related Health Impacts	4-2

4.2.1.1	Selecting air pollution health endpoints to quantify	4-2

4.2.1.2	Quantifying Cases of Ozone-Attributable Premature Mortality	4-4

4.2.1.3	Economic Valuation	4-5

4.2.1.4	Benefit-per-Ton Estimates	4-7

4.2.2	Ozone Vegetation Effects	4-9

4.2.3	Ozone Climate Effects	4-9

4.3	VOC-Related Ozone Benefits Results	4-9

4.4	Characterization of Uncertainty in the Monetized VOCBenefits	4-13

4.5	Health Effects from Exposure to Hazardous Air Pollutants (HAP)	4-13

4.5.1	Benzene	4-14

4.5.2	Hexane	4-14

4.5.3	Toluene	4-15

4.5.4	2,2,4-Trimethylpentane	4-15

4.5.5	Napthalene	4-15

4.5.6	Ethylbenzene	4-16

4.5.7	Xylenes	4-16

4.5.8	Cumene	4-17

4.5.9	Other Air Toxics	4-17

4.6	Climate Impacts	4-17

4.7	Total Monetized Benefits	4-36

5	Economic Impact Analysis and Distributional Assessments	5-1

5.1	Introduction	5-1

5.2	Economic Impact Analysis	5-1

vi


-------
5.2.1	Description of Approach/Model/Framework	5-2

5.2.1.1	Gasoline MarketModel	5-2

5.2.1.2	Model Baseline	5-3

5.2.1.3	Model Parameters	5-4

5.2.2	Economic Impact Results	5-5

5.2.2.1	Market-Level Results	5-5

5.2.2.2	Welfare Change Estimates	5-5

5.2.2.3	Limitations	5-9

5.3	Small Business Impacts Analysis	5-9

5.3.1	Small Business National Overview	5-11

5.3.2	Small Entity Economic Impacts	5-12

5.3.2.1	Main Screening Analysis	5-12

5.3.2.2	Supplementary Screening Analysis	5-15

5.4	Employment Impact Analysis	5-18

6	Comparison of Benefits and Costs	6-1

6.1	Results	6-1

6.2	Uncertainties and Limitations	6-6

7	References	7-1

8	Appendix A: Detailed Market Impact Tables	8-1

8.1	Proposed Options	8-1

8.1.1	Price Impacts	8-1

8.1.2	Quantity Impacts	8-2

8.2	Less Stringent Alternative Options	8-3

8.2.1	Price Impacts	8-3

8.2.2	Quantity Impacts	8-4

8.3	More Stringent Alternative Options	8-5

8.3.1	Price Impacts	8-5

8.3.2	Quantity Impacts	8-6

9	Appendix B: Discounted Cost For the Proposed Options Tables by Rule	9-1

9.1	NSPSXXA	9-1

9.2	MACTR	9-3

9.3	GACT6B	9-5

vii


-------
LIST OF TABLES

Table 1-1: Current and Proposed Standards for NESHAP GACT 6B	1-6

Table 1-2: Short-term and Long-Term Monetized Benefits, Compliance Costs, and Net Benefits for Proposed

Amendments to GACT 6B (dollars in million 2019$)a	1-8

Table 1-3: Current and Proposed Standards for MACT R	1-9

Table 1-4: Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits, Compliance Costs, and Emissions Reductions for

Proposed Amendments to MACT R (dollars in million 2019$)a	1-10

Table 1-5: Current and Proposed Standards for NSPS XX and Proposed NSPS XXa	1-11

Table 1-6: Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits, Compliance Costs, and Emissions Reductions for

Proposed NSPS XXa (dollars in million 2019$)a	1-12

Table 1-7: Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits, Compliance Costs, and Emissions Reductions for

Proposed NSPS XXa and Proposed Amendments to MACT R and GACT 6B (dollars in million 2019$)a	1-13

Table 2-1: Pipeline Shipments PADD to PADD (Thousand Barrels)	2-2

Table 2-2: Bulk Gasoline Terminal Working Capacity (Thousand Gallons)	2-4

Table 2-3: Refiner Gasoline Volume by Sales Type (thousand gallons/day)	2-7

Table 2-4: 15 Largest Gasoline Distribution Parent Companies by Facilities Owned	2-8

Table 2-5: NAICS 424710 - Enterprise Size by Employment (2017)	2-11

Table 2-6: U.S. Gasoline Consumption, 2009-2019 (billion gallons)	2-12

Table 2-7: Motor Gasoline Projected Consumption by Sector, Selected Years (quadrillion BTUs)	2-13

Table 2-8: Gasoline Expenditure as Share of Household Expenditure	2-14

Table 2-9: Gasoline Expenditure as a Share of Household Expenditure by Region (2019-2020)	2-14

Table 2-10: Percentage Change in Gasoline Spending and CPI-U	2-14

Table 2-11: Distribution of Gasoline Consumption by PADD, 2009-2019	2-15

Table 2-12: Gasoline Price by PADD ($2019/gallon)	2-18

Table 2-13: Gasoline Price by Refiner Disposition, Average All Grades ($2019/gallon)	2-19

Table 2-14: Motor Gasoline Growth Rates by Sector, 2020-2050	2-20

Table 2-15: AEO 2021 Baseline Gasoline Projections, 2026-2040	2-20

Table 3-1: Regulated Facilities by Rule	3-2

Table 3-2: Cargo Tank Vapor-Tightness Certification Standards Examined in this RIA (inches WC)	3-7

Table 3-3: NSPS XXa Projected Affected Facilities, 2026-2040	3-13

Table 3-4: Model Plant Distribution and Configurations	3-14

Table 3-5: Assumed Distribution of Controls at Bulk Plants	3-14

Table 3-6: Current and Proposed Standards for NESHAP GACT 6B	3-18

Table 3-7: Regulatory Options Examined in this RIA - GACT 6B	3-19

Table 3-8: Current and Proposed Standards for MACT R	3-21

Table 3-9: Regulatory Options Examined in this RIA - MACT R	3-21

Table 3-10: Current and Proposed Standards for NSPS XX and NSPS XXa	3-22

Table 3-11: Regulatory Options Examined in this RIA - NSPS XXa	3-23

Table 3-12: Baseline Emissions in 2027 (Short Tons)	3-24

Table 3-13: NSPS XXa Baseline Emissions (Tons), 2026-2040	3-24

Table 3-14: Emissions Reductions for Regulatory Options, Tons per Year	3-26

Table 3-15: Emissions Reductions for Regulatory Options (Tons), NSPS XXa, 2026-2040	3-26

Table 3-16: GACT 6B Secondary Emissions Increases (short tons)	3-27

Table 3-17: NSPS XXa Secondary Emissions Increases, Proposed/Less Stringent/More Stringent Options (Tons).. 3-
27

Table 3-18: Proposed Options, Detailed Impacts by Emissions Point (peryear), GACT 6B	3-28

Table 3-19: Less Stringent Options, Detailed Impacts by Emissions Point (peryear), GACT 6B	3-29

Table 3-20: More Stringent Options, Detailed Impacts by Emissions Point (peryear), GACT 6B	3-30

Table 3-21: Proposed Options, Detailed Impacts by Emissions Point (peryear), MACTR	3-31

Table 3-22: Less Stringent Options, Detailed Impacts by Emissions Point (per year), MACT R	3-31

Table 3-23: More Stringent Options, Detailed Impacts by Emissions Point (per year), MACT R	3-32

Table 3-24: Proposed Options, Detailed Impacts by Emissions Point (2027), NSPS XXa	3-33

Table 3-25: Less Stringent Options, Detailed Impacts by Emissions Point (2027), NSPS XXa	3-33

Table 3-26: More Stringent Options, Detailed Impacts by Emissions Point (2028), NSPS XXa	3-34

viii


-------
Table 3-27: Estimated Annual Costs for Regulatory Options	3-35

Table 3-28: Present and Equivalent Annual Values of Compliance Costs of Regulatory Options, 2026-2040 (million

2019$, discounted to 2022)	 3-36

Table 3-29: Discounted Capital and O&M Costs, Proposed Options, for NSPS XXa, MACT R, and GACT 6B,

2026-2040 (million 2019$, discounted to 2022)	 3-38

Table 3-30: Discounted Costs, Proposed Options, for NSPS XXa, MACT R, and GACT 6B, 2026-2040 (million

2019$, discounted to 2022)	 3-39

Table 4-1: Human Health Effects of Ambient Ozone	4-4

Table 4-2: Gasoline Distribution: Short-term and Long-term Benefit per Ton Estimates of Ozone-Attributable

Premature Mortality and Illness for the Proposal, 2025-2040 ($2019)	4-10

Table 4-3: Gasoline Distribution GACT 6B: Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits Estimates of Ozone-

Attributable Premature Mortality and Illness (million 2019$)a b c	4-11

Table 4-4: Gasoline Distribution MACT R: Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits Estimates of Ozone-

Attributable Premature Mortality and Illness (million 2019$)a b c	4-11

Table 4-5: Gasoline Distribution NSPS XXa: Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits Estimates of Ozone-

Attributable Premature Mortality and Illness (million 2019$)a b c	4-12

Table 4-6: Gasoline Distribution All Rules: Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits Estimates of Ozone-

Attributable Premature Mortality and Illness (million 2019$)a b c	4-12

Table 4-7: Interim Global Social Cost of Carbon Values, 2026-2040 (2019$/Metric Ton CO2)	4-28

Table 4-8: Projected Discounted Global CO2 Disbenefits under the Proposed Amendments, GACT 6B, 2026-2040

(millions 2019$)	4-32

Table 4-9: Projected Discounted Global CO2 Benefits under the Proposed Amendments, NSPS XX, 2026-2040

(millions 2019$)	4-34

Table 4-10: Summary of Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits PV/EAV for GACT 6B, 2026-2040,

(million 2019$)	4-37

Table 4-11: Summary of Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits PV/EAV for MACT R, 2026-2040, (million

2019$)	4-38

Table 4-12: Summary of Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits PV/EAV for NSPS XXa, 2026-2040,

(million 2019$)	4-39

Table 4-13: Summary of Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits PV/EAV for All Rules, 2026-2040, (million

2019$)	4-40

Table 5-1: Description of Gasoline Market Model	5-3

Table 5-2: AEO 2021 Baseline Gasoline Projections, 2026-2040	5-4

Table 5-3: Welfare Impacts of Proposed Options, 2026-2040 (Discounted to 2022, million 2019$)	5-6

Table 5-4: Welfare Impacts of Less Stringent Alternative Options, 2026-2040 (Discounted to 2022, million 2019$)

	5-7

Table 5-5: Welfare Impacts of More Stringent Alternative Options, 2026-2040 (Discounted to 2022, million 2019$)

	5-8

Table 5-6: SBA Size Standards by NAICS Code	5-10

Table 5-7: Summary Statistics of Potentially Affected Entities	5-11

Table 5-8: Worst-Case Costs by Model Plant	5-12

Table 5-9: Distribution of Estimated Compliance Costs by Rule and Size for Proposed Options ($2019)	5-13

Table 5-10: Compliance Cost-to-Sales Ratio Distributions for Small Entities, Proposed Options	5-13

Table 5-11: Compliance Cost-to-Sales Ratio Thresholds for Small Entities - Proposed Options	5-14

Table 5-12: NAICS 424710 - Small Entity Impacts	5-17

Table 6-1: Summary of Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits, Compliance Costs, and Net Benefits

PV/EAV for GACT 6B, 2026-2040 (million 2019$, discounted to 2022)	6-2

Table 6-2: Summary of Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits, Compliance Costs, and Net Benefits

PV/EAV for MACT R, 2026-2040 (million 2019$, discounted to 2022)	6-3

Table 6-3: Summary of Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits, Compliance Costs, and Net Benefits

PV/EAV for NSPS XXa, 2026-2040 (million 2019$, discounted to 2022)	6-4

Table 6-4: Summary of Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits, Compliance Costs, and Net Benefits

PV/EAV for All Rules, 2026-2040 (million 2019$, discounted to 2022)	6-5

Table 8-1: Projected Change in Price, Proposed Options (2019 cents/gallon of gasoline)	8-1

Table 8-2: Projected Percentage Change in Price, Proposed Options	8-1

Table 8-3: Projected Change in Quantity, Proposed Options (gallons of gasoline)	8-2

IX


-------
Table 8-4: Percentage Change in Quantity, Proposed Options	8-2

Table 8-5: Projected Change in Price, Less Stringent Alternative Options (2019 cents/gallon of gasoline)	8-3

Table 8-6: Projected Percentage Change in Price, Less Stringent Alternative Options	8-3

Table 8-7: Projected Change in Quantity, Less Stringent Alternative Options (gallons of gasoline)	8-4

Table 8-8: Percentage Change in Quantity, Less Stringent Alternative Options	8-4

Table 8-9: Projected Change in Price, More Stringent Alternative Options (2019 cents/gallon of gasoline)	8-5

Table 8-10: Projected Percentage Change in Price, More Stringent Alternative Options	8-5

Table 8-11: Projected Change in Quantity, More Stringent Alternative Options (gallons of gasoline)	8-6

Table 8-12: Percentage Change in Quantity, More Stringent Alternative Options	8-6

Table 9-1: Discounted Capital and O&M Costs, Proposed Options, forNSPS XXa, 2026-2040 (million $2019)... 9-1

Table 9-2: Discounted Costs, Proposed Options, for NSPS XXa, 2026-2040 (million $2019)	9-2

Table 9-3: Discounted Capital and O&M Costs, Proposed Options, forMACT R, 2026-2040 ($2019)	9-3

Table 9-4: Discounted Costs, Proposed Options, for MACT R, 2026-2040 ($2019)	9-4

Table 9-5: Discounted Capital and O&M Costs, Proposed Options, for GACT 6B, 2026-2040 ($2019)	9-5

Table 9-6: Discounted Costs, Proposed Options, for GACT 6B, 2026-2040 ($2019)	9-6

x


-------
LIST OF FIGURES

Figure 2-1: Petroleum Administration Defense Districts for Retail Gasoline	2-3

Figure 2-2: System of Pipelines, Ports, and Waterways for Petroleum Product Transportation	2-4

Figure 2-3: The Gasoline Distribution System	2-5

Figure 2-4: Gasoline Distribution Physical Structure and Marketing Channels	2-6

Figure 2-5: Price of Gasoline by Component	2-17

Figure 2-6: Gasoline Price by PADD	2-18

Figure 4-1: Social Cost of Carbon in 2030 [2016$ / metric ton CO2]	4-35

XI


-------
1 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

1.1 Background

The U.S Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) is proposing amendments to the
National Emissions Standards for Hazardous Air Pollutants (NESHAP) for Gasoline Distribution
facilities and the Standards of Performance for Bulk Gasoline Terminals. The EPA is proposing
to revise NESHAP requirements for storage tanks, loading operations, and equipment leaks to
reflect cost-effective developments in practices, process, or controls of hazardous air pollutants
(HAP). The EPA is also proposing New Source Performance Standards (NSPS) to reflect best
system of emissions reduction for emissions of volatile organic compounds (VOC) from loading
operations and equipment leaks at bulk gasoline terminals. The proposal also includes revisions
related to emissions during periods of startup, shutdown, and malfunction (SSM); additional
requirements for electronic reporting of performance test results, performance evaluation reports,
and compliance reports; revisions to monitoring and operating requirements for control devices;
and other minor technical improvements. The proposed amendments would cumulatively reduce
projected emissions of HAP from this source category by 2,220 short tons (English tons) per year
and would reduce emissions of VOC by 45,400 short tons per year. The great majority of these
projected HAP and VOC emission reductions would occur as a result of the proposed area source
NESHAP technology review.

1.1.1 NESHAP subparts R and BBBBBB

The statutory authority for the proposed NESHAP amendments is provided by sections
112 and 301 of the Clean Air Act (CAA), as amended (42 U.S.C. 7401 et seq.). Section 112 of
the CAA establishes a two-stage regulatory process to develop standards for emissions of HAP
from stationary sources. Generally, the first stage involves establishing technology-based
standards and the second stage involves evaluating those standards that are based on maximum
achievable control technology (MACT) to determine whether additional standards are needed to
address any remaining risk associated with HAP emissions. This second stage is commonly
referred to as the "residual risk review." In addition to the residual risk review, the CAA also
requires the EPA to review standards set under CAA section 112 every 8 years and revise the
standards as necessary taking into account any "developments in practices, processes, or control

1-1


-------
technologies." This review is commonly referred to as the "technology review," and is the
subject of this proposal.

In the first stage of the CAA section 112 standard setting process, the EPA promulgates
technology-based standards under CAA section 112(d) for categories of sources identified as
emitting one or more of the HAP listed in CAA section 112(b). Sources of HAP emissions are
either major sources or area sources, and CAA section 112 establishes different requirements for
major source standards and area source standards. "Major sources" are those that emit or have
the potential to emit 10 tons per year (tpy) or more of a single HAP or 25 tpy or more of any
combination of HAP. All other sources are "area sources." For major sources, CAA section
112(d)(2) provides that the technology-based NESHAP must reflect the maximum degree of
emission reductions of HAP achievable (after considering cost, energy requirements, and non-air
quality health and environmental impacts). These standards are commonly referred to as MACT
standards. CAA section 112(d)(3) also establishes a minimum control level for MACT standards,
known as the MACT "floor " In certain instances, as provided in CAA section 112(h), the EPA
may set work practice standards in lieu of numerical emission standards. The EPA must also
consider control options that are more stringent than the floor. Standards more stringent than the
floor are commonly referred to as beyond-the-floor standards. For area sources, CAA section
112(d)(5) allows the EPA to set standards based on generally available control technologies or
management practices (GACT standards) in lieu of MACT standards. For categories of major
sources and any area source categories subject to MACT standards, the second stage in standard-
setting focuses on identifying and addressing any remaining {i.e., "residual") risk pursuant to
CAA section 112(f) and concurrently conducting a technology review pursuant to CAA section
112(d)(6). MACT standards were finalized for the Gasoline Distribution source category in
1994. The residual risk and technology review was finalized in 2006. GACT standards were set
for the Gasoline Distribution area source category in 2008.

The sources affected by the current area source NESHAP for the Gasoline Distribution
source category subpart BBBBBB (GACT 6B) are bulk gasoline terminals, bulk gasoline plants,
and pipeline facilities. A bulk gasoline terminal is defined as "any gasoline storage and
distribution facility that receives gasoline by pipeline, ship or barge, or cargo tank and has a
gasoline throughput of 20,000 gallons per day or greater." A bulk gasoline plant is defined as
"any gasoline storage and distribution facility that receives gasoline by pipeline, ship or barge, or

1-2


-------
cargo tank, and subsequently loads the gasoline into gasoline cargo tanks for transport to
gasoline dispensing facilities and has a gasoline throughput of less than 20,000 gallons per day."
A pipeline breakout station is defined as "a facility along a pipeline containing storage vessels
used to relieve surges or receive and store gasoline from the pipeline for re-injection and
continued transportation by pipeline or to other facilities." A pipeline pumping station is defined
as "a facility along a pipeline containing pumps to maintain the desired pressure and flow of
product through the pipeline, and not containing gasoline storage tanks other than surge control
tanks." Emissions from loading racks at large bulk gasoline terminals (those with gasoline
throughput of 250,000 gallons per day or greater) are controlled by vapor collection and
processing systems meeting 80 milligrams total organic carbon (TOC) per liter of gasoline
loaded (mg/L) and the cargo tanks being loaded must be certified to be vapor tight. Small bulk
gasoline terminals and bulk gasoline plants must use submerged filling when loading gasoline.
Emissions from storage vessels with a design capacity greater than or equal to 75 cubic meters
(m3) are controlled by equipment designed to capture and control emissions. Equipment leaks are
repaired upon detection using audio, visual, and olfactory (AVO) methods.

The sources affected by the current major source NESHAP for the Gasoline Distribution
source category subpart R (MACT R) are bulk gasoline terminals and pipeline breakout stations.
A bulk gasoline terminal is defined as "any gasoline facility which receives gasoline by pipeline,
ship, or barge, and has a gasoline throughput greater than 75,700 liters per day."1 A pipeline
breakout station is defined as "a facility along a pipeline containing storage vessels used to
relieve surges or receive and store gasoline from the pipeline for reinjection and continued
transportation by pipeline or to other facilities." Emissions from loading racks are controlled by
vapor collection and processing systems meeting 10 mg/L and the cargo tanks being loaded must
be certified to be vapor tight. Emissions from storage vessels with a design capacity greater than
or equal to 75 m3 are controlled by equipment designed to capture and control emissions.
Equipment leaks are required to be repaired upon detection using AVO methods.

1.1.2 NSPS subpart XX

The EPA's authority for the NSPS proposal is CAA section 111, which governs the
establishment of standards of performance for stationary sources. CAA section 111(b)(1)(A)

'75.700 liters per day is approximately equal to 20,000 gallons per day.

1-3


-------
requires the EPA Administrator to list categories of stationary sources that in the Administrator's
judgement cause or contribute significantly to air pollution that may reasonably be anticipated to
endanger public health or welfare. The EPA must then issue performance standards for new (and
modified or reconstructed) sources in each source category pursuant to CAA section
111(b)(1)(B). These standards are referred to as new source performance standards, or NSPS.
The EPA has the authority under CAA section 111(b) to define the scope of the source
categories, determine the pollutants for which standards should be developed, set the emission
level of the standards, and distinguish among classes, type, and sizes within categories in
establishing the standards.

Section 111(b)(1)(B) of the CAA requires the EPA to "at least every 8 years review and,
if appropriate, revise" new source performance standards. Section 111(a)(1) of the CAA provides
that performance standards are to "reflect the degree of emission limitation achievable through
the application of the best system of emission reduction which (taking into account the cost of
achieving such reduction and any non-air quality health and environmental impact and energy
requirements) the Administrator determines has been adequately demonstrated." We refer to this
level of control as the best system of emission reduction or "BSER." The term "standard of
performance" in CAA 111(a)(1) makes clear that the EPA is to determine both the BSER for the
regulated sources in the source category and the degree of emission limitation achievable
through application of the BSER. The EPA must then, under CAA section 111(b)(1)(B),
promulgate standards of performance for new sources that reflect that level of stringency. The
NSPS for Bulk Gasoline Terminals was promulgated in 1983.

The sources affected by the current NSPS for the Bulk Gasoline Terminals source
category subpart XX are bulk gasoline terminals that commenced construction or modification
after December 17, 1980. NSPS subpart XX defines bulk gasoline terminals as "any gasoline
facility which receives gasoline by pipeline, ship or barge, and has a gasoline throughput greater
than 75,700 liters per day." Emissions from loading racks at bulk gasoline terminals are
controlled by vapor collection and processing systems meeting 35 mg/L and the cargo tanks
being loaded must be certified to be vapor tight.2 Equipment leaks are required to be repaired
upon detection using AVO methods. Emissions from storage vessels are regulated under a

2 Allowance is provided to meet 80 mg/L for affected facilities with an "existing vapor processing system."

1-4


-------
separate NSPS (40 CFR part 60, subpart K, Ka, or Kb). In this action, EPA is proposing a new
subpart at part 60, subpart XXa.

1.2	Market Failure

Many regulations are promulgated to correct market failures, which otherwise lead to a
suboptimal allocation of resources within a market. Air quality and pollution control regulations
address "negative externalities" whereby the market does not internalize the full opportunity cost
of production borne by society as public goods such as air quality are unpriced.

While recognizing that the optimal social level of pollution may not be zero, HAP and
VOC emissions impose costs on society, such as negative health and welfare impacts, that are
not reflected in the market price of the goods produced through the polluting process. For this
regulatory action the good produced is gasoline. If the process of transporting gasoline from
refineries to consumers pollutes the atmosphere, the social costs imposed by the pollution will
not be borne by the polluting firm but rather by society as a whole. Thus, the producer is
imposing a negative externality, or a social cost from these emissions, on society. The
equilibrium market price of gasoline may fail to incorporate the full opportunity cost to society
of consuming the gasoline. Consequently, absent a regulation or some other action to limit
emissions, producers will not internalize the negative externality of pollution due to emissions
and social costs will be higher as a result. This regulation will work towards addressing this
market failure by causing affected producers to begin internalizing the negative externality
associated with HAP and VOC emissions.

1.3	Results for Proposed Action

1.3.1 Baseline for the Regulation

The impacts of regulatory actions are evaluated relative to a baseline that represents the
world without the regulatory action. In this RIA, the EPA presents results for the proposed
amendments to NESHAP GACT 6B and MACT R and proposed NSPS XXa. Throughout this
document, the EPA focuses the analysis on the proposed requirements that result in quantifiable
compliance cost or emissions changes compared to the baseline. For each rule and most
emissions sources, EPA assumed each facility achieved emissions control meeting current
standards, and estimated emissions and cost relative to this baseline. We calculate cost and

1-5


-------
emissions reductions relative to the baseline for the period 2026-2040. This time frame spans the
projected first year of full implementation of the proposed NESHAP amendments (under the
assumption that the proposed action is finalized in 2023) through the lifetime of the longest-lived
capital equipment expected to be installed as a result of the proposed amendment. We assume the
proposed NSPS XXa takes effect in 2022 and, given the relatively small impacts of the proposed
rule compared to those from the proposed NESHAP amendments, analyze their impacts over the
period 2026-2040.

1,3.2 GACT6B

1.3.2.1 Options Examined in this RIA

The technology review for NESHAP GACT 6B identified improvements in
environmental control technology and emissions performance of loading racks, storage tanks,
equipment leak detection and repair, and cargo tank vapor tightness. As a result, the EPA is
proposing decisions concerning the technology review to revise requirements for storage tanks,
loading operations, and equipment leaks. The current and proposed standards for each emissions
source and facility covered by GACT 6B are listed in Table 1-1 below.

Table 1-1: Current and Proposed Standards for NESHAP GACT 6B	

Emissions Source

Facility

Current Standard

Proposed Standard

Loading Racks

Small Bulk Terminal
(<250,000 gallons per day
(gpd), >20,000 gpd)

Large Bulk Terminal
(>250,000 gpd)

Bulk Plant
(< 20,000 gpd)

Submerged fill

80 mg/L
Submerged fill

Submerged fill

35 mg/L

Require vapor
balancing system

Storage Tanks

Large Tanks

Compliance with NSPS Kb
except for secondary seal
on internal floating roof
(IFR) tanks and some
fittings controls

Require NSPS Kb
fitting controls for
external floating roof
(EFR) Tanks and LEL
monitoring for IFR
Tanks



Small Tanks

Require fixed roof tanks

Require fixed roof tanks

Equipment Leaks

Bulk Terminals, Bulk Plants,
Pipeline Breakout Stations,
Pipeline Pumping Stations

Monthly AVO inspections

Annual instrument
monitoring

1-6


-------
Cargo Tank Vapor-
tightness

Bulk Terminals and Bulk
Plants

Maximum allowable
pressure loss during
certification of 3" water
column (WC) for large
bulk terminals only

Maximum allowable
pressure loss during
certification of 0.5" -
1.25" WC

1.3.2.2 Overview of Costs and Benefits for the Proposed Options

The proposed amendments to GACT 6B constitute an economically significant regulatory
action. This action is an economically significant regulatory action because it likely to have an
annual effect on the economy of $100 million or more in any one year or adversely affect in a
material way the economy, a sector of the economy, productivity, competition, jobs, the
environment, public health or safety, or state, local, or tribal governments or communities.
Specifically, the proposed amendments to GACT 6B are projected to reduce VOC emissions by
about 40,000 short tons per year. VOC emissions, in conjunction with NOx and in the presence
of sunlight, form ground-level ozone (O3). The EPA monetized the projected benefits of
reducing VOC emissions in terms of the value of avoided ozone-attributable deaths and illnesses,
both short- (ST) and long-term (LT). The equivalent annualized value of monetized ozone
benefits related to VOC emissions reductions is greater than $100 million per year, as seen in
Table 1-2, based on both short- and long-term avoided ozone-attributable deaths and illnesses.

Table 1-2 also presents projected emissions reductions, climate disbenefits, compliance
costs, and net benefits from the proposed amendments to GACT 6B. The projected climate
disbenefits are caused by increased electricity usage associated with emissions controls on
loading racks at bulk terminals, which are expected to cause secondary emissions increases of
CO2, NO2, SO2, and CO. Only the disbenefits associated with increased CO2 emissions have
been monetized for this RIA. Certain control options analyzed in this RIA lead to gasoline vapor
recovery, which has been monetized as product recovery credits. Net compliance costs are
calculated as total compliance costs minus product recovery credits. For a discussion of product
recovery, see Section 3.2.6. The net compliance costs of the proposed amendments to GACT 6B
are negative, meaning the value of projected product recovery exceeds the projected compliance
costs. Net benefits are projected to be positive using short- and long-term estimates of ozone
health benefits and both 3 percent and 7 percent social discount rates. Further, while benefits
from HAP reductions and VOC reductions outside of the ozone season have not been monetized
for this action, EPA expects these benefits are positive. The unmonetized effects also include

1-7


-------
disbenefits from secondary emissions increases of NO2, SO2, and CO resulting from increased
electricity usage associated with emissions controls on loading racks at bulk gasoline terminals.
As mentioned earlier, we calculate cost and emissions reductions relative to the baseline for the
period 2026-2040.

Table 1-2: Short-term and Long-Term Monetized Benefits, Compliance Costs, and Net
Benefits for Proposed Amendments to GACT 6B (dollars in million 2019$3)a	



3 Percent Discount Rate

7 Percent Discount Rate



PV

EAV

PV

EAV

Health Benefits'3

$180(ST)
and

$15(ST)
and

$110 (ST)
and

$12 (ST)
and



$1,500 (LT)

$130 (LT)

$900 (LT)

$99 (LT)

Climate Disbenefits (3%)°

$28

$2.3

$28

$2.3

Net Compliance Costs'1

($70)

($5.0)

($42)

($5.0)

Compliance Costs

$140

$12

$98

$11

Value of Product Recovery

$210

$17

$140

$16

Net Benefits

$230 (ST)
and

$18(ST)
and

$130(ST)
and

$15(ST)
and



$1,500 (LT)

$130 (LT)

$910 (LT)

$100 (LT)

Emissions Reductions
(short tons)



2026-2040 Total



VOC





605,000



HAP





31,000



Secondary Emissions Increases
(short tons)



2026-2040 Total



C02





490,000



N02





290



S02





3.5



CO





1,300



a Totals may not sum due to independent rounding. Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise
noted.

b Monetized benefits include ozone related health benefits associated with reductions in VOC emissions. The health
benefits are associated with several point estimates and are presented at real discount rates of 3 and 7 percent for
both short- (ST) and long-term (LT) benefits. The two benefits estimates are separated by the word "and" to signify
that they are two separate estimates. The estimates do not represent lower- and upper-bound estimates. Disbenefits
from additional C02 emissions resulting from application of control options are monetized and included in the table
as climate disbenefits. Benefits from HAP reductions and VOC reductions outside of the ozone season remain
unmonetized and are thus not reflected in the table. The unmonetized effects also include disbenefits resulting from
the secondary impact of an increase in NO2, SO2, and CO emissions. Please see Section 4.6 for more discussion of
the climate disbenefits.

0 Climate disbenefits are based on changes (increases) in CO2 emissions and are calculated using four different
estimates of the social cost of carbon (SC-CO2) (model average at 2.5 percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount
rates; 95th percentile at 3 percent discount rate). For the presentational purposes of this table, we show the
disbenefits associated with the average SC-CO2 at a 3 percent discount rate, but the Agency does not have a single

3 When necessary, dollar figures in this RIA have been converted to 2019$ using the annual GDP Implicit Price
Deflator values in the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis' (BEA) NIPA Table 1.1.9 found at found at
.

1-8


-------
central SC-CO2 point estimate. We emphasize the importance and value of considering the disbenefits calculated
using all four SC-CO2 estimates; the additional disbenefit estimates range from PV (EAV) $5.4 million ($0.5
million) to $84 million ($7.0 million) from 2026-2040 for the proposed amendments. Please see
Table 4-7 for the full range of SC-CO2 estimates. As discussed in Chapter 4, a consideration of climate disbenefits
calculated using discount rates below 3 percent, including 2 percent and lower, is also warranted when discounting
intergenerational impacts.

dNet compliance costs are the engineering control costs minus the value of recovered product. A negative net
compliance costs occurs when the value of the recovered product exceeds the compliance costs.

1,3.3 MALT R

1.3.3.1 Options Examined in this RIA

The technology review for NESHAP MACT R identified improvements in environmental
control technology and emissions performance of storage tanks, equipment leak detection and
repair, and cargo tank vapor tightness. As a result, the EPA is proposing decisions concerning the
technology review to revise requirements for storage tanks, equipment leak detection and repair,
and cargo tank vapor tightness. The current and proposed standards for each emissions source
and facility covered by MACT R are listed in Table 1-3 below.

Table 1-3: Current and Proposed Standards for MACT R

Emissions Source

Facility

Current Standard

Proposed Standard

Loading Racks

Bulk Terminal

10 mg/L

10 mg/L

Storage Tanks

Bulk Terminals and Pipeline
Breakout Stations

Compliance with NSPS
Kb except for some fitting
controls

Require NSPS Kb
fitting controls for
EFR Tanks and LEL
monitoring for IFR
Tanks

Equipment Leaks

Bulk Terminals and Pipeline
Breakout Stations

Monthly AVO
inspections

Semiannual instrument
monitoring

Cargo Tank Vapor-
tightness

Bulk Terminals

Maximum allowable
pressure loss during
certification of 1" - 2.5"
WC

Maximum allowable
pressure loss during
certification of 0.5" -
1.25" WC

1.3.3.2 Overview of Costs and Benefits for the Proposed Options

The proposed amendments to MACT R do not constitute an economically significant
regulatory action. This action is not an economically significant regulatory action because it is
not likely to have an annual effect on the economy of $100 million or more in any one year or
adversely affect in a material way the economy, a sector of the economy, productivity,
competition, jobs, the environment, public health or safety, or state, local, or tribal governments
or communities. Table 1-4 presents projected monetized health benefits, climate disbenefits,

1-9


-------
compliance costs, and emissions reductions from the proposed amendments to MACT R. No
secondary emissions impacts are expected from the proposed amendments to MACT R because
there are no proposed changes to standards for loading racks at major source bulk gasoline
terminals. Therefore, there are therefore no projected climate or other disbenefits. Net benefits
are projected to be negative using short-term ozone benefits and positive based on long-term
ozone benefits using both a 3 percent and a 7 percent social discount rate. Also, while benefits
from HAP reductions and VOC reductions outside of ozone season have not been monetized for
this action, EPA expects these benefits are positive. As mentioned earlier, we calculate cost and
emissions reductions relative to the baseline for the period 2026-2040.

Table 1-4: Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits, Compliance Costs, and
Emissions Reductions for Proposed Amendments to MACT R (dollars in million 2019$)a



3 Percent Discount Rate

7 Percent Discount Rate



PV

EAV

PV

EAV

Health Benefits'3

$9.9 (ST)
and

$0.83 (ST)
and

$5.6 (ST)
and

$0.65 (ST)
and



$81 (LT)

$6.8 (LT)

$48 (LT)

$5.3 (LT)

Net Compliance Costs0

$23

$2.0

$15

$1.8

Compliance Costs

$34

$2.9

$23

$2.6

Value of Product Recovery

$11

$1.0

$8

$0.9

Net Benefits

($13) (ST)
and

($1.2) (ST)
and

($9.4) (ST)
and

($1.2) (ST)
and



$58 (LT)

$4.8 (LT)

$33 (LT)

$3.5 (LT)

Emissions Reductions



2026-2040 Total



(short tons)





VOC





32,000



HAP





2,010



Secondary Emissions Increases
(short tons)



2026-2040 Total



C02





0



no2





0



S02





0



CO





0



a Totals may not sum due to independent rounding. Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise
noted.

b Monetized benefits include ozone related health benefits associated with reductions in VOC emissions. The health
benefits are associated with several point estimates and are presented at real discount rates of 3 and 7 percent for
both short- (ST) and long-term (LT) benefits. The two benefits estimates are separated by the word "and" to signify
that they are two separate estimates. The estimates do not represent lower- and upper-bound estimates. Benefits
from HAP reductions and VOC reductions outside of the ozone season remain unmonetized and are thus not
reflected in the table.

0 Net compliance costs are the engineering control costs minus the value of recovered product. A negative net
compliance costs occurs when the value of the recovered product exceeds the compliance costs.

1-10


-------
1,3,4 NSPS XX

1.3.4.1 Options Examined in this RIA

The review of the Standards of Performance for Bulk Gasoline Terminals (NSPS XX)
identified improvements in environmental control technology and emissions performance of
loading racks, equipment leak detection and repair, and cargo tanks. As a result, the EPA is
proposing NSPS XXa and requirements for loading operations, equipment leaks, and cargo tank
vapor tightness. The current and proposed standards for each emissions source and facility
covered by NSPS XX and proposed NSPS XXa are listed in Table 1-5 below.

Table 1-5: Current and Proposed Standards for NSPS XX and Proposed NSPS XXa	

Emissions Source

Facility

Current Standard

Proposed Standard

Loading Racks

Bulk Terminal - New

Bulk Terminal -
Modified/Reconstructed

35 mg/L
35 mg/L

1 mg/L
10 mg/L

Equipment Leaks

Bulk Terminal

Monthly AVO
inspections

Quarterly instrument
monitoring

Cargo Tank Vapor-
tightness

Bulk Terminal

Maximum allowable
pressure loss during
certification of 3" water
column (WC)

Maximum allowable
pressure loss during
certification of 0.5" -
1.25" WC

1.3.4.2 Overview of Costs and Benefits for the Proposed Options

The proposed NSPS XXa does not constitute an economically significant regulatory
action. This action is not an economically significant regulatory action because it is not likely to
have an annual effect on the economy of $100 million or more in any one year or adversely
affect in a material way the economy, a sector of the economy, productivity, competition, jobs,
the environment, public health or safety, or state, local, or tribal governments or communities.
Table 1-6 presents projected monetized benefits, climate disbenefits, compliance costs, and
emissions reductions from the proposed NSPS XXa. The projected climate disbenefits are caused
by increased electricity usage associated with emissions controls on loading racks at bulk
terminals, which are expected to cause secondary emissions increases of CO2, NO2, SO2, and
CO. Only the disbenefits associated with increased CO2 emissions have been monetized for this
RIA. Net benefits are projected to be negative based on short-term ozone benefits and positive
based on long-term ozone benefits using both a 3 percent and a 7 percent social discount rate.

1-11


-------
Also, while benefits from HAP reductions and VOC reductions outside of ozone season have not
been monetized for this action, EPA expects these benefits are positive. The unmonetized effects
also include disbenefits from secondary emissions increases of NO2, SO2, and CO resulting from
increased electricity usage associated with emissions controls on loading racks at bulk terminal.
We calculate cost and emissions reductions relative to the baseline for the period 2026-2040.

Table 1-6: Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits, Compliance Costs, and
Emissions Reductions for Proposed NSPS XXa (dollars in million 2019$)a	



3 Percent Discount Rate

7 Percent Discount Rate



PV

EAV

PV

EAV

Health Benefits'3
Climate Disbenefits (3%)°

$29 (ST)

and
$240 (LT)
$4.4

$2.4 (ST)

and
$20 (LT)
$0.37

$16 (ST)

and
$130 (LT)
$4.4

$1.7 (ST)

and
$15 (LT)
$0.37

Net Compliance Costs'1

$9.0

$0.7

$5.0

$0.6

Compliance Costs

$41

$3.4

$26

$2.9

Value of Product Recovery
Net Benefits

$32
$16 (ST)

and
$230 (LT)

$2.7
$1.3 (ST)

and
$19 (LT)

$21
$6.6 (ST)

and
$120 (LT)

$2.3
$0.73 (ST)

and
$14 (LT)

Emissions Reductions



2026-2040 Total



(short tons)





VOC





97,000



HAP





4,020



Secondary Emissions Increases
(short tons)

2026-2040 Total



C02





74,000



N02





50



S02





42



CO





0



a Totals may not sum due to independent rounding. Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise
noted.

b Monetized benefits include ozone related health benefits associated with reductions in VOC emissions. The health
benefits are associated with several point estimates and are presented at real discount rates of 3 and 7 percent for
both short- (ST) and long-term (LT) benefits. The two benefits estimates are separated by the word "and" to signify
that they are two separate estimates. The estimates do not represent lower- and upper-bound estimates. Benefits
from HAP reductions and VOC reductions outside of the ozone season remain unmonetized and are thus not
reflected in the table. The unmonetized effects also include disbenefits resulting from the secondary impact of an
increase in, NO2, SO2, and CO emissions. Therefore, monetized climate disbenefits associated with the increased
CO2 emissions are not presented in the benefit-cost analysis of this proposed action conducted pursuant to E.O.
12866. Please see Section 4.6 for more discussion of the climate disbenefits.

0 Climate disbenefits are based on changes (increases) in CO2 emissions and are calculated using four different
estimates of the social cost of carbon (SC-CO2) (model average at 2.5 percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount
rates; 95th percentile at 3 percent discount rate). For the presentational purposes of this table, we show the
disbenefits associated with the average SC-CO2 at a 3 percent discount rate, but the Agency does not have a single
central SC-CO2 point estimate. We emphasize the importance and value of considering the disbenefits calculated
using all four SC-CO2 estimates; the additional disbenefit estimates range from PV (EAV) $0.78 million ($0.08

1-12


-------
million) to $13 million ($1.1 million) from 2026-2040 for the proposed amendments. Please see Table 4-7 for the
full range of SC-CO2 estimates. As discussed in Chapter 4, a consideration of climate disbenefits calculated using
discount rates below 3 percent, including 2 percent and lower, is also warranted when discounting intergenerational
impacts.

dNet compliance costs are the engineering control costs minus the value of recovered product. A negative net
compliance costs occurs when the value of the recovered product exceeds the compliance costs.

1.3.5 All Rules

1.3.5.1 Overview of Costs and Benefits for All Rules Cumulatively

Table 1-7 presents projected cumulative impacts for the proposed NSPS XXa and
proposed amendments to MACT R and GACT 6B. The cumulative net compliance costs of the
proposed amendments are negative, meaning the value of projected product recovery exceeds the
projected compliance costs. Net benefits are projected to be positive using short- and long-term
estimates of ozone health benefits and both 3 percent and 7 percent social discount rates. Further,
while benefits from HAP reductions and VOC reductions outside of ozone season have not been
monetized for this action, EPA expects these benefits are positive. The unmonetized effects also
include disbenefits from secondary emissions increases of NO2, SO2, and CO resulting from
increased electricity usage associated with emissions controls on loading racks at bulk terminal.
As mentioned earlier, we calculate cost and emissions reductions relative to the baseline for the
period 2026-2040.

Table 1-7: Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits, Compliance Costs, and
Emissions Reductions for Proposed NSPS XXa and Proposed Amendments to MACT R
and GACT 6B (dollars in million 2019$)a	



3 Percent Discount Rate 7 Percent Discount Rate



PV

EAV PV

EAV

Health Benefits'3

$220 (ST)
and

$19(ST) $130(ST)
and and

$15 (ST)
and



$1,800 (LT)

$150 (LT) $1,100 (LT)

$120 (LT)

Climate Disbenefits (3%)°

$32

$2.7 $32

$2.7

Net Compliance Costs'1

($38)

($2.4) ($22)

($2.7)

Compliance Costs

$220

$18 $150

$17

Value of Product Recovery

$250

$20 $170

$19

Net Benefits

$230 (ST)
and

$19 (ST) $120 (ST)
and and

$15 (ST)
and



$1,800 (LT)

$150 (LT) $1,090 (LT)

$120 (LT)

Emissions Reductions



2026-2040 Total



(short tons)





VOC



730,000



HAP



37,000



Secondary Emissions Increases



2026-2040 Total



1-13


-------
(short tons)

C02
N02
S02
CO

560,000
340
46
1,300

a Totals may not sum due to independent rounding. Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise
noted.

b Monetized benefits include ozone related health benefits associated with reductions in VOC emissions. The health
benefits are associated with several point estimates and are presented at real discount rates of 3 and 7 percent for
both short- (ST) and long-term (LT) benefits. The two benefits estimates are separated by the word "and" to signify
that they are two separate estimates. The estimates do not represent lower- and upper-bound estimates. Benefits
from HAP reductions and VOC reductions outside of the ozone season remain unmonetized and are thus not
reflected in the table. The unmonetized effects also include disbenefits resulting from the secondary impact of an
increase in NO2, SO2, and CO emissions. Please see Section 4.6 for more discussion of the climate disbenefits.
0 Climate disbenefits are based on changes (increases) in CO2 emissions and are calculated using four different
estimates of the social cost of carbon (SC-CO2) (model average at 2.5 percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount
rates; 95th percentile at 3 percent discount rate). For the presentational purposes of this table, we show the
disbenefits associated with the average SC-CO2 at a 3 percent discount rate, but the Agency does not have a single
central SC-CO2 point estimate. We emphasize the importance and value of considering the disbenefits calculated
using all four SC-CO2 estimates; the additional disbenefit estimates range from PV (EAV) $6.2 million ($0.6
million) to $97 million ($8.1 million) from 2026-2040 for the proposed amendments. Please see Table 4-7 for the
full range of SC-CO2 estimates. As discussed in Chapter 4, a consideration of climate disbenefits calculated using
discount rates below 3 percent, including 2 percent and lower, is also warranted when discounting intergenerational
impacts.

dNet compliance costs are the engineering control costs minus the value of recovered product. A negative net
compliance costs occurs when the value of the recovered product exceeds the compliance costs.

1.4 Organization of this Report

The remainder of this report details the methodology and the results of the RIA. Chapter
2 presents a profile of the gasoline distribution industry. Chapter 3 describes emissions,
emissions control options, and engineering costs. Chapter 4 presents the benefits analysis,
including a qualitative discussion of the unmonetized benefits associated with HAP emissions
reductions and monetization of the disbenefits associated with climate (CO2) emissions
increases. Chapter 5 presents analyses of economic impacts, impacts on small businesses, and a
narrow analysis of employment impacts. Chapter 6 presents a comparison of benefits and costs.
Chapter 7 contains the references for this RIA. Chapter 8 (Appendix A) presents detailed tables
from the market impact analysis found in Section 5.2.2. Chapter 9 (Appendix B) presents
discounted cost tables by year and individual rule.

1-14


-------
2 INDUSTRY PROFILE

2.1	Introduction

Gasoline plays an important role in the U.S. economy. According to the Energy
Information Administration (EIA)4, gasoline consumption accounted for 59 percent of
transportation sector energy consumption, 44 percent of petroleum consumption, and 16 percent
of energy consumption in the U.S. in 2020. Over 90 percent of U.S. gasoline consumption fuels
light-duty vehicles. The Gasoline Distribution sector delivers finished motor gasoline and
blending components from petroleum refineries to end-users. Most of the firms in the sector fall
under NAICS classification 424710 (Petroleum Bulk Stations and Terminals) and 486910
(Transportation of Refined Petroleum Products). This section provides an overview of the
gasoline distribution industry. Portions of this section are adapted from the Economic Impact
Analysis for the Gasoline Distribution Industry (Area Sources) (EPA, 2008).

2.2	Supply Side

Finished gasoline and blending components are shipped from petroleum refineries via
pipeline, tanker, or barge to bulk distribution facilities that store and dispense gasoline. A variety
of downstream marketing arrangements (i.e., wholesale and retail) deliver gasoline to the
consumer. This section contains three parts: an overview of the gasoline distribution network, a
description of the marketing arrangements which deliver gasoline from bulk distribution
facilities to consumers, and a brief examination of industry organization.

2.2.1 The Gasoline Distribution Network

The gasoline distribution network consists of storage and transfer facilities that move
gasoline from its production to its end consumption. Petroleum refineries produce finished motor
gasoline and gasoline blending components from crude oil, which are then shipped via pipeline,
barge, or tanker truck to bulk gasoline distribution terminals. Gasoline is the primary product
produced by petroleum refineries, with each barrel (42 gallons) of crude oil processed into about

4 Energy Information Administration. Gasoline explained: Use of Gasoline.
. accessed 1/20/2022.

2-1


-------
20 gallons of gasoline5. The Gulf Coast region is the petroleum refinery center of the U.S., with
the 5 largest refineries in either Texas or Louisiana6.

Most gasoline is shipped from the refinery via pipeline (-61 percent in 20197'8), with the
largest flows moving from the Gulf Coast to the East Coast and Midwest (see Table 2-1). Figure
2-2 provides a map of the pipeline and water shipping paths typically used for refined petroleum
in the U.S. Along the pipeline, two main types of facilities regulate the flow of gasoline:
pumping stations, which contain pumps used to maintain the desired pressure and flow of
product through the pipeline, and breakout stations, which contain storage tanks to relieve surges
and store product for re-injection and continued transportation to bulk distribution terminals.

Table 2-1: Pipeline Shipments PADD to PADD (Thousand Barrels)	

From

To

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

East Coast
Midwest

Midwest

East Coast
Gulf Coast
Rocky Mountain

Gulf Coast

East Coast
Midwest
Rocky Mountain

Midwest
West Coast

West Coast

N/A

6,100

1,700
700
2,800

82,000
7,500

4,000
3,600

2,200

1,600
1,200
3,200

40,000
9,400

3,800
4,400

1,200

4,000
1,400
1,900

36,000
7,600

4,200
3,900

1,000

4,300
1,500
2,300

35,000
7,000

3,700
5,700

990

5,000
1,600
2,500

21,000
7,800

4,200
5,100

Source: Energy Information Administration. Movements by Pipeline between Pad Districts.
.

Once at a bulk distribution terminal, finished gasoline is transferred directly to a storage
tank, while blending components may first be mixed to produce fuel of a desired specification.

5	Energy Information Administration.

. Accessed 1/24/2022.

6	Energy Information Administration. Table 5: Refiners' Total Operable Atmospheric Crude Oil Distillation

Capacity, . accessed 1/20/2022.

7	Energy Information Administration. Movements by Pipeline between PAD Districts.

. accessed 1/20/2022.

8	Energy Information Administration. Movements by Pipeline, Tanker, Barge, and Rail between PAD Districts.

. Accessed 1/20/2022

2-2


-------
Due to its proximity to large population centers, the largest volume of bulk gasoline storage
capacity is in the East Coast Petroleum Administration Defense District (PADD)9 (see Table 2-2:
Bulk Gasoline Terminal Working Capacity), followed by the Gulf Coast PADD. Gasoline is
loaded via loading racks from storage tanks into large tanker trucks or railcars cargo tanks
(typically 8,000-10,000-gallon capacity), which transport gasoline either to retail stations for
final sale to consumer or intermediate storage facilities called bulk plants. Bulk plants store
gasoline and transfer it via loading rack to tanker trucks for transport to retail gasoline stations or
end consumers. They are similar in staicture to bulk distribution terminals but contain less
storage capacity and handle less throughput. See Figure 2-3 for a general depiction of the
gasoline distribution network.

pA00

PADD 1A:
New
England

PADD 1B
Central ,
Atlantic i

€

P

Seis*

w



PADD 1:
East
Coast

PADD 5:
West Coast

FL

PADD 3:
Gulf Coast

ei?

PADD - Petroleum Administration for Defense Distncts

Figure 2-1: Petroleum Administration Defense Districts for Retail Gasoline

Source: U.S. Energy Informalion Administration

9 The Petroleum Administration for Defense Districts (PADDs) are geographic aggregations of the 50 States and the
District of Columbia into five districts: PADD 1 is the East Coast, PADD 2 the Midwest, PADD 3 the Gulf Coast,
PADD 4 the Rocky Mountain Region, and PADD 5 the West Coast. For a map of PADD districts, see Figure 2-1.

2-3


-------
Table 2-2: Bulk Gasoline Terminal Working Capacity (Thousand Gallons)

Year

East Coast

Midwest

Gulf Coast

Rocky Mountain

West Coast

U.S.
Total

2011

71,000

51,000

50,000

3,900

25,000

200,000

2012

74,000

50,000

54,000

3,900

24,000

210,000

2013

77,000

51,000

56,000

3,900

24,000

210,000

2014

80,000

51,000

58,000

3,800

24,000

220,000

2015

82,000

50,000

59,000

3,800

24,000

220,000

2016

84,000

50,000

55,000

3,900

24,000

220,000

2017

84,000

51,000

60,000

4,100

25,000

220,000

2018

84,000

52,000

62,000

4,100

25,000

230,000

2019

87,000

52,000

66,000

4,100

26,000

240,000

2020

89,000

52,000

74,000

4,100

24,000

240,000

Source: Energy Information Administration, Form EIA-815 ''Monthly Bulk Terminal and Blender Report",

2011-2020.

Petroleum products

(pipelines, ports, waterways)

Figure 2-2: System of Pipelines, Ports, and Waterways for Petroleum Product
Transportation

Source: U.S. Energy Information Administration

2-4


-------
imported crude oil	^rage

tanker
or barge

£"1

		\ __ » —ft.—

refinery A	I	tanker truck gas station

pipeline!

domestic	pipeline

crude oil

JB	bulk		1	_ _

	~terminal	J	—, rffiPO

storage	common storage	00 00

pipeline	tanker truck 9 station

ifi&B/

refinery B 		"f,k"ru^

«0

or barge

refinery
storage

imported crude oil		

Source: U.S. Energy Information Administration	eia^

Figure 2-3: The Gasoline Distribution System

Source: U.S. Energy Information Administration10

2,2.2 Downstream Marketing Arrangements for Refined Petroleum Products

Once refined petroleum products leave the refinery, they reach consumers through one or
more marketing channels. This final step in the supply of refined petroleum products includes
two components: wholesale distribution (from product terminals to retail outlets) and retail
distribution (to final consumers). Truck transportation is the most common delivery method of
gasoline to retail outlets.

There are four primary gasoline marketing channels for wholesale distribution of
gasoline. Three of these constitute direct distribution of product:

•	Refiner-operated retail outlet: Refiners directly distribute gasoline to their own retail outlets.

•	Lessee dealer: Retail outlets are owned by the wholesale distributor but leased to a gasoline
dealer.

•	Independent retailer: Retail outlets are owned and operated by independent "open" dealers.
The fourth channel comprises indirect distribution of product:

10 See .

2-5


-------
• Jobber: Distributors purchase directly from refiners and then sell products to retail outlets.

The variety of marketing channels illustrates that firms are not all vertically integrated;
that is, they are not involved in all stages of gasoline operations from gasoline production,
distribution, and ultimate sales to consumers (see Figure 2-4). Table 2-3 shows data for refiner
disposition of gasoline by volume to the bulk (sales by contract larger than a truckload), dealer
tankwagon (DTW) (price set by the refiner for a truckload of gasoline delivered to a retail
gasoline station), and rack (rack sales distributed to jobbers) levels. An increasing percentage of
gasoline is being though rack sales to jobbers, with -88 percent sold via that method in 2019.

Physical Structure

Pipeline
(Barge. Rail)

Marketing Channels

Refiner-
operated
Retail

Lessee
Dealer

Retail Price

Consumer

Consumer

Jobber

Jobber

Consumer

Independent
Retailer

Refinery



Port



Refiner



Refiner



Refiner



Refiner

Rack Price





Independent
Retailer

Dealer



Dealer



1

I

1

Retail Price

i

1

Retail Price

J

Consumer

Figure 2-4: Gasoline Distribution Physical Structure and Marketing Channels

Source: U.S. Department of Energy, Energy Information Administration (EIA). 2003. "2003 California Gasoline
Price Study: Final Report." Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Energy, Energy Information
Administration.

2-6


-------
Table 2-3: Refiner Gasoline Volume by Sales Type (thousand gallons/day)

Year

DTW

Rack

Bulk

Total Wholesale

2009

40,000

230,000

41,000

311,000

2010

36,000

230,000

43,000

309,000

2011

30,000

230,000

33,000

293,000

2012

27,000

240,000

28,000

295,000

2013

28,000

240,000

25,000

293,000

2014

24,000

240,000

21,000

285,000

2015

23,000

250,000

22,000

295,000

2016

23,000

260,000

21,000

304,000

2017

22,000

260,000

18,000

300,000

2018

22,000

260,000

20,000

302,000

2019

21,000

270,000

15,000

306,000

Source: Energy Information Administration. U.S. Motor Gasoline Refiner Sales Volume.
. 1/3/2022.

2,2,3 Industry Organization

EPA constructed a facility list for the Gasoline Distribution source category based on the
2017 National Emissions Inventory (NEI), the Toxics Release Inventory, information from the
original Gasoline Distribution NESHAP, Bulk Terminal list of petrochemical storage facilities
from the Internal Revenue Service, the Office of Enforcement and Compliance Assurance's
Enforcement and Compliance History Online (ECHO) tool (https://echo.epa.gov), and the
Energy Information Administration (EIA). This created an initial list of 1,838 facilities in the
Gasoline Distribution source category (hereafter referred to as the "facility list"). The
construction of the facility list is described in the preamble for the proposed action. EPA
ultimately identified the ultimate parent company along with revenue and employment
information for 1,705 facilities on the list11. While this facility list does not cover all facilities in
the sector, it is useful to provide a broad overview. This section provides background on the
ultimate parent companies that own the facilities comprising EPA's list.

2.2.3.1 Concentration and Vertical Integration

Table 2-4 lists the revenue and employment information for the 15 companies in the
Gasoline Distribution sector that own the most facilities. Collectively, these firms own -52
percent of the facilities on the list and averaged $88 billion in revenue in 2019. All these firms
are multinational in operation and vertically integrated, operating in at least two of the following

11 Revenue and employment information was collected through manual search of D&B Hoover's database in 2021.

2-7


-------
sectors: petroleum extraction, petroleum refining, refined petroleum product transportation,
refined petroleum product storage and distribution, or refined petroleum sales. The first two
firms on the list provide good examples. Buckeye Partners is heavily active in both
transportation and storage of refined petroleum products, owning over 6,000 miles of pipeline
and over 100 petroleum product terminals12. Marathon Petroleum Corporation is vertically
integrated along most of the gasoline supply chain, owning refineries, pipeline facilities, bulk
petroleum terminals, and retail gasoline stations13. In addition to providing transport and storage
of gasoline, at least 8 of these companies also engage in major petroleum refining or extraction
operations (Marathon Petroleum Corporation, Phillips 66, Citgo, Royal Dutch Shell, Koch
Industries, Chevron, Saudi Aramco, and Exxon Mobil). The top 50 ultimate parent companies on
the Facility List own 79 percent of the facilities on the list and averaged $42 billion in revenue in
2019, with a minimum company revenue of $44 million. This shows that the Gasoline
Distribution sector is characterized by a substantial degree of vertical integration and is
suggestive of a moderately concentrated industry (while there are many active firms, a small
minority of them control more than half the market).

Table 2-4: 15 Largest Gasoline Distribution Parent Companies by Facilities Owned

Company

Revenue
(million 2019$)

Employment

Facilities Owned

Hercules Intermediate Holdings LLC
(Buckeye Partners LP)

$4,100

1,800

125

Marathon Petroleum Corporation

$120,000

60,000

117

Kinder Morgan Inc

$11,000

10,000

97

Magellan Midstream Partners

$2,400

1,800

91

Energy Transfer LP

$38,000

12,000

65

NGL Energy Partners LP

$7,400

1,400

65

Nustar Energy LP

$1,400

1,400

59

Phillips 66

$64,000

14,000

54

PDV America Inc

$26,000

4,100

48

(Citgo)

Royal Dutch Shell

$340,000

83,000

36

Koch Industries

$110,000

100,000

30

Chevron Corporation

$93,000

48,000

26

Apex Holding Company

$210

1,200

26

Saudi Aramco

$330,000

68,000

25

Exxon Mobil Corporation

$180,000

74,000

25

12	, accessed 1/20/2022.

13	, accessed 1/20/2022.

2-8


-------
Source: EPA Gasoline Distribution Facility List, D&B Hoover's Database.

The National Renewable Energy Laboratory (NREL) (2016) used non-public data from the Oil
Price Information Service (OPIS) to characterize terminal ownership by five company types
(major examples of the company type described in parentheses):

•	Oil: Vertically integrated companies that explore and drill for oil and refine it. These
companies may also own pipelines (Chevron).

•	Pipeline: Companies that own pipelines and lease storage space to customers at terminals
(Buckeye Partners, Kinder Morgan, Magellan)

•	Refinery: Companies that own refineries and terminals. These companies may also own
pipeline (Marathon Petroleum, Royal Dutch Shell, Saudi Aramco, Phillips 66).

•	Terminal: Companies that own one or more terminals, but do not own pipelines or
refineries.

•	Other

NREL found that, while comprising only 55 companies, firms in the Oil, Pipeline, and Refinery
groups owned about 65 percent of terminals and about 70 percent of terminal capacity. Terminal
companies owned roughly 31 percent of terminals and 29 percent of capacity, with the remainder
of both owned by firms in the Other category.

2.2.3.2 Entry Barriers

Entry into the pipeline business requires significant capital investments. In addition, it
often takes years to acquire the necessary approvals and complete construction of a new pipeline.
An entrant into product terminals is faced with relatively high capital costs to acquire and install
storage tanks and to design, acquire, and install a loading rack. Once operating, however,
terminals exhibit scale economies, because as storage volume increases, the cost of operating
declines. Other entry barriers for terminals include zoning and environmental permit issues,
which can make the time span for opening a new terminal lengthy. One deterrent to entry into
product terminals is excess capacity. Existing capacity can meet periods of high terminal demand

2-9


-------
without large price increases for terminal service; incentives to invest in new terminal capacity
tend to be reduced without these price signals.

2.2.3.3 Employment

The US Census Bureau collects data on NAICS classifications 424710 (Petroleum Bulk
Stations and Terminals) and 486910 by enterprise size (see Table 2-5 for NAICS 424710; data
on NAICS 486910 is very noisy due to the small number of firms, so we report aggregates
below). This information does not reflect ultimate ownership and does not provide complete
coverage of bulk gasoline storage and transportation facilities, but still provides a reasonable
guide to the number of facilities and the employment level in the sector. In 2017, approximately
66,000 people were employed in about 4,000 establishments classified as Petroleum Bulk
Stations and Terminals (NAICS 424710) by the US Census. This is down from 2012, when the
Census reported 74,600 people employed in about 4,500 establishments14. In combination with
Table 2-2, which reports increasing terminal storage capacity per facility over time, this suggests
consolidation in gasoline storage and transportation as facilities close and existing facilities
expand capacity (evidence of the economies of scale discussed in the previous section).

About 4,700 people were employed in 675 establishments classified as engaging in
Transportation of Refined Petroleum Products (NAICS 486910)15. This is roughly flat from 2012
(4,960 people employed in 560 establishments)16. Taken together approximately, about 71,000
people in the Gasoline Distribution sector across NAICS 424710 and NAICS 486910, although
this may miss employment at some smaller bulk plants that are not large enough to be classified
under NAICS 424710 or facilities which engage in bulk storage and transportation of gasoline as
a secondary business function.

14	US Census Bureau. County Business Patterns 2012 and Economic Census 2012.
. Accessed 1/24/2022.

15	US Census. County Business Patterns 2017 and Economic Census 2017.
. Accessed 1/24/2022.

16	US Census Bureau. County Business Patterns 2012 and Economic Census 2012.
. Accessed 1/24/2022.

2-10


-------
Table 2-5: NAICS 424710

- Enterprise Size by Employment (2017)



Enterprise Size

Firms

Establishments

Employment

Average
Receipts
(million
2019$)

<5 employees

508

511

1,099

$4

5-9 employees

415

425

2,731

$18

10-14 employees

267

292

2,922

$24

15-19 employees

144

170

2,126

$30

20-24 employees

121

139

2,233

$41

25-29 employees

83

102

1,708

$29

30-34 employees

65

76

1,546

$46

35-39 employees

60

79

1,788

$59

40-49 employees

92

123

2,766

$44

50-74 employees

115

176

4,552

$196

75-99 employees

76

145

3,834

$297

100-149 employees

83

159

4,344

$90

150-199 employees

57

136

3,819

$203

200-299 employees

69

169

4,267

$111

300-399 employees

27

77

3,719

$347

400-499 employees

15

65

2,131

$467

500-749 employees

36

96

3,422

$1,100

750-999 employees

16

85

1,511

$980

1,000-1,499 employees

22

157

2,449

$511

1,500-1,999 employees

7

232

1,800

$881

2,000-2,499 employees

6

35

1,092

$3,662

2,500-4,999 employees

20

206

4,212

$2,766

5,000+ employees

30

295

6,190

$7,882

Source: US Census. County Business Patterns 2017 and Economic Census 2017.
. Accessed 1/24/2022.

Note: Based on Census definitions, an establishment is a physical location at which business is conducted or
services/industrial operations are performed. A firm is a business organization consisting of one or more
domestic establishments in the same geographic area and industry that were specified under common
ownership or control. An enterprise may have establishments in many different industries, so employment for
an enterprise within NAICS 424710 may be lower than total employment at an enterprise.

2.3 Demand Side

Table 2-6 below shows U.S. gasoline consumption from 2009 to 2019. The U.S.
consumed about 143 billion gallons of gasoline in 2019. The Federal Highway Administration
(FWHA) distinguishes gasoline consumption by use: highway and nonhighway. In 2019, about
93 percent was consumed for highway use. The remaining 7 percent is for nonhighway use (i.e.,
lawn and garden equipment and marine uses)17.

17 Department of Transportation. Federal Highway Administration. Highway Statistics 2019.

2-11


-------
Table 2-6: U.S. Gasoline Consumption, 2009-2019 (billion gallons)

Year

Quantity

2009

137.92

2010

137.86

2011

134.18

2012

133.46

2013

135.56

2014

136.76

2015

140.70

2016

143.22

2017

142.98

2018

143.01

2019

142.71

The Energy Information Administration projects motor gasoline consumption by sector in
their "Annual Energy Outlook 2021" (AEO 2021). This structure is consistent with the National
Energy Modeling System (NEMS) used to generate forecasts for AEO 2021. Motor gasoline
consumption is classified by three end-use sectors:

•	Commercial: Commercial-sector consumption encompasses business
establishments that are not engaged in industrial or transportation activities.

•	Industrial: The industrial sector includes energy consumption for fuels and
feedstocks for 15 manufacturing industries and 6 nonmanufacturing industries.
This includes agriculture, mining, construction, and manufacturing industries.

•	Transportation: The transportation sector includes consumption of transportation-
sector fuels by transportation mode (light-duty vehicle, air travel, freight transport).
The NEMS Transportation Sector Demand Module models a variety of vehicle types,
sizes, fuels, and technology configurations for each class of transportation.

Transportation consumes the bulk of gasoline energy usage, and this is projected to continue
over the next two decades as shown below in Table 2-7.

2-12


-------
Table 2-7: Motor Gasoline Projected Consumption by Sector, Selected Years (quadrillion
BTUs)	

Sector

2021

Share

2026

Share

2031

Share

2040

Share

Commercial

0.35

2.19%

0.37

2.32%

0.37

2.41%

0.37

2.48%

Industrial

0.26

1.61%

0.29

1.83%

0.31

2.00%

0.34

2.26%

Transportation

15.48

96.20%

15.23

95.85%

14.70

95.59%

14.33

95.26%

Light-duty vehicles

14.20

91.72%

13.93

91.46%

13.38

91.02%

12.86

89.74%

Commercial light trucks

0.55

3.55%

0.55

3.61%

0.55

3.74%

0.60

4.16%

Recreation Boats

0.16

1.03%

0.16

1.05%

0.15

1.04%

0.14

1.01%

Freight Trucks

0.53

3.42%

0.53

3.51%

0.55

3.76%

0.64

4.50%

Transit and school buses

0.13

0.84%

0.19

1.25%

0.20

1.35%

0.20

1.37%

Source: Energy Information Administration. Annual Energy Outlook 2021. Table 2 and Table 36. Feb. 3,
2021. . Accessed 1/3/2022.

2,3,1 Factors that Influence Gasoline Consumption

Transportation choices are a function of tastes, income, gasoline prices, and prices of
related goods. Personal automobiles and trucks are the dominant mode of travel in U.S.,
accounting for about 87 percent of passenger miles traveled in 201918. According to the Bureau
of Labor Statistics' Consumer Expenditure Survey, the share of household expenditure was flat
from 2016 to 2019 at around 3.3 percent (see Table 2-8) but did fall about 25 percent from 2019
to 2020 as people reduced travel during the Covid-19 pandemic19. This expenditure share is
similar across region (see Table 2-9), with consumers in the northeast spending a slightly smaller
share of income on gasoline in 2019-2020. There is also a seasonality to gasoline demand, with
both the quantity of gasoline consumed and the price of gasoline tending to rise through the
spring and peak at the end of summer20.

18	University of Michigan Center for Sustainable Systems. Personal Transportation Factsheet. 2021.
.

19	Bureau of Labor Statistics. Consumer Expenditure Survey. .
Accessed 1/21/2022.

20	Energy Information Administration. Gasoline explained: gasoline price fluctuations. 9/9/2021.
. Accessed 1/20/2022.

2-13


-------
Table 2-8: Gasoline Expenditure as Share of Household Expenditure

Year

Expenditure Share

2016

3.30%

2017

3.30%

2018

3.40%

2019

3.30%

Source: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Consumer Expenditure Surveys 2016-2019. September 2020.
. Accessed 1/24/2022.

Table 2-9: Gasoline Expenditure as a Share of Household Expenditure by Region (2019-
2020)	

All Consumer Units, United States

2.9%

Northeast

2.3%

Midwest

3.0%

South

3.2%

West

3.1%

Source: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Consumer Expenditure Survey.

. September 2021. Accessed
1/24/2022.

Gasoline expenditure is largely driven by price changes. Table 2-10 shows the percentage
change in gasoline expenditure along with the percentage in a price index for gasoline (CPI-U
Gasoline). The table shows both the price of gasoline is relatively volatile year-to-year, and
gasoline expenditure changes roughly proportionally with price. This suggests that consumer
demand for gasoline is relatively inelastic. This is in line with the research on the price elasticity
of demand for gasoline (see Section 5.2.1.3).

Table 2-10: Percentage Change in Gasoline Spending and CPI-U

Year

Gasoline Expenditure

CPI-U
Gasoline

2008

14.1

16.1

2009

-27.1

-26.9

2010

7.4

18.3

2011

24.7

26

2012

4

3.3

2013

-5.1

-2.9

2014

-5.5

-4

2015

-16.1

-27.2

2016

-8.7

-11.3

2017

2.8

13.1

2018

7.4

13.4

2019

-0.9

-3.5

Source: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Consumer Expenditure Survey 2008-2019.
. Accessed 1/24/2022.

2-14


-------
Consumers can respond to price changes in gasoline in two general ways. First, they may
reduce the number of vehicle miles traveled. If the relative price of gasoline remains higher for
long periods, consumers may also consider adjusting their vehicle choice or home location to
mitigate the effects of higher prices. For example, they may purchase vehicles with better fuel
economy or buy a home closer to work or shopping. It is also likely that current trends towards
increased remote work spurred by the Covid-19 pandemic allow greater flexibility with respect
to commuting, which could cause people to be more responsive to gasoline prices. They could
also switch from gasoline-power vehicles to alternative modes of transportation such as mass
transit and/or switch to vehicles that use alternative fuels, such as electric or hybrid-electric
vehicles. Electric and hybrid-electric vehicles, while currently owned by about 7 percent of U.S.
car owners, constitute a growing share of the U.S. market; registrations of such vehicles
increased almost four-fold from 2016 to 202121.

2.4 Market Conditions

2.4.1 Consumption

American consumption of gasoline increased about 3.5 percent from 2009 to 2019 and
was roughly flat from 2016 to 2019 (see Table 2-6). Table 2-11 shows the geographic
distribution of consumption by PADD. This distribution was very stable over the period, with the
largest share occurring in the East Coast PADD (36 percent in 2019).

Table 2-11: Distribution of Gasoline Consumption by PADD, 2009-2019	

Year

East Coast

Midwest

Gulf Coast

Rocky Mountain

West Coast

2009

36%

28%

16%

3%

17%

2010

36%

28%

15%

3%

17%

2011

36%

28%

15%

3%

17%

2012

35%

28%

15%

4%

17%

2013

35%

29%

16%

3%

17%

2014

34%

29%

16%

3%

18%

2015

35%

28%

16%

3%

17%

2016

35%

29%

16%

3%

17%

2017

35%

29%

15%

3%

17%

2018

35%

29%

15%

3%

17%

21 Desilver, Drew. Today's electric vehicle market: Slow growth in U.S., faster in China, Europe. Pew Research
Center. 6/7/2021. . Accessed 1/24/2022.

2-15


-------
Year

East Coast

Midwest

Gulf Coast

Rocky Mountain

West Coast

2019

36%

29%

15%

4%

18%

Source: Energy Information Administration. Supply and Disposition.
. 4/30/2021.

2.4.2 Prices

The price of gasoline includes the cost of crude oil, distribution and marketing, refining
costs and profits, and federal and state taxes (see Figure 2-5), with the cost of crude oil
accounting for the largest share (56 percent on average from 2011 to 2020). The other
components tend to make of roughly equal shares. The Energy Information Administration22
reports that as of July 2021 federal excise taxes on gasoline were 18.4 cents per gallon, with state
excise taxes averaging 30.6 cents per gallon. States taxes vary widely, from a low of 8 cents per
gallon in Alaska to a high of 58 cents per gallon in Pennsylvania in 201923. In total, taxes account
for about 16 percent of the price of gasoline, with distribution, marketing, refining costs and
profits accounting for the remaining 28 percent.

22	Energy Information Administration.
. Accessed 1/21/22.

23	Federal Highway Administration. Highway Statistics Series 2019.
. Accessed 1/24/2022.

2-16


-------
2011-2020
average retail price
$2.85/gallon

14%

14%

16%

56%

distribution
and marketing

refining costs
and profits

federal and
state taxes

crude oil

2020
average retail price
$2.17/gallon



10%



25%





22%

43%



Figure 2-5: Price of Gasoline by Component

Source: Energy Information Administration. Gasoline and Diesel Fuel Update.

Gasoline prices also vary geographically (see Table 2-12 and Figure 2-6). The main
sources of variation in price by region are state taxes and distance from Gulf Coast petroleum
refineries. Gasoline is cheapest in the Gulf Coast region and increases in price as it travels north
and up the east coast. Prices are highest on the West Coast, where gasoline taxes are high and
pipeline access to Gulf Coast refineries is poor. Certain regions are also required to sell
reformulated gasoline due to elevated levels of smog (ozone) and HAP. Reformulated gasoline
tends to cost 30 to 35 cents more per gallon than conventional24, with reformulated gasoline sales
concentrated on the west coast and in dense, urban areas.

24 See Desilver (2019): Gasoline costs more these days, but price spikes have a long history and happen for a host of
reasons. Pew Research Center. 12/9/2021. . Accessed 1/24/2022.

2-17


-------
Rocky Mountain

$3.37 per gallon
T

Midwest
$3.03 per gallon

T

West Coast
$4.14

per gallon

per gallon

Central
Atlantic

$3.42

per gallon

East Coast

New
England

$3.37

per gallon

per gallon

eia1

Figure 2-6: Gasoline Price by PADD

Note: Includes taxes.

Source: Energy Information Administration. ElA-878 Motor Gasoline Price Survey. 1/3/2022.

Table 2-12: Gasoline Price by PADD ($2019/gallon)

Year

U.S.

East Coast

Midwest

Gulf Coast

Rocky Mountain

West Coast

2009

$2.04

$2.03

$1.98

$1.93

$1.97

$2.61

2010

$2.43

$2.42

$2.38

$2.31

$2.41

$3.25

2011

$3.13

$3.14

$3.09

$2.99

$3.03

$3.48

2012

$3.28

$3.29

$3.21

$3.10

$3.16

$3.41

2013

$3.24

$3.26

$3.18

$3.06

$3.15

$3.36

2014

$3.17

$3.20

$3.10

$2.97

$3.13

$2.81

2015

$2.35

$2.31

$2.25

$2.10

$2.31

$2.47

2016

$2.12

$2.12

$2.02

$1.91

$2.08

$2.78

2017

$2.43

$2.43

$2.31

$2.20

$2.40

$3.24

2018

$2.76

$2.72

$2.62

$2.49

$2.82

$3.37

2019

$2.69

$2.59

$2.54

$2.35

$2.74

$2.92

Source: Energy Information Administration. Weekly Retail Gasoline
and Diesel Prices. 1/3/2022.

. Accessed 1/24/2022.

2-18


-------
The type of supply-side marketing arrangement affects the wholesale price of gasoline,
which indirectly affects retail prices paid by consumers. Refiner-operated stations receive a co-
op price—an unobserved, internal transfer price. Lessee and independent retailers receive a
DTW price—this price is offered under contract by the wholesaler. Jobbers receive what is
known as the rack price. Table 2-13 shows wholesale prices of gasoline by method of refiner
disposition. DTW prices include transportation costs and are thus higher than bulk (sales on
contract larger than one truckload) and rack prices.

Table 2-13: Gasoline Price by Refiner Disposition, Average All Grades ($2019/gallon)

Year

DTW

Rack

Bulk

2009

$1.61

$1.49

$1.42

2010

$1.96

$1.85

$1.78

2011

$2.61

$2.50

$2.42

2012

$2.78

$2.60

$2.55

2013

$2.67

$2.54

$2.51

2014

$2.58

$2.41

$2.35

2015

$2.00

$1.58

$1.52

2016

$1.65

$1.35

$1.29

2017

$1.93

$1.60

$1.58

2018

$2.37

$1.91

$1.91

2019

$2.44

$1.82

$1.74

Source: Energy Information Administration. Refiner Gasoline Prices by Grade and Sales Type. 1/3/2022.
. Accessed 1/24/2022.

2.4.3 Trends and Projections

AEO 2021 estimates that the average annual growth rate for gasoline consumption will
be almost completely flat (0.00 percent) from 2020-2050. As shown in Table 2-14, increases in
commercial and industrial gasoline usage is projected to be canceled out by a slight decrease in
transportation usage, driven by a decrease in gasoline consumption by light-duty vehicles. Table
2-15 contains gasoline price and quantity projections from 2026-2040. These years, as discussed
in chapter 3, comprise the baseline period of analysis for this RIA. Gasoline prices rose by about
a dollar per gallon on average from 2021 to 2022 ($2.18 to $3.02) according to the Energy
Information Administration's Short-Term Energy Outlook (STEO 2022)25. The STEO is
currently projecting an average price per gallon of $3.06 in 2022 and $2.81 in 2023.

25 Energy Information Administration. Short Term Energy Outlook, .
1/11/2022.

2-19


-------
Table 2-14: Motor Gasoline Growth Rates by Sector, 2020-2050

Sector

Average Annual Growth Rate



Commercial



0.50%

Industrial



1.60%

Transportation



-0.10%



Light-duty vehicles

-0.20%



Commercial light trucks

0.80%



Recreation Boats

-0.50%



Freight Trucks

1.60%



Transit and school buses

3.30%

Total



0.00%

Source: Energy Information Administration. Annual Energy Outlook 2021. Table 2 and Table 36. Feb. 3, 2021.
. Accessed 1/3/2022.

Table 2-15: AEO 2021 Baseline Gasoline Projections, 2026-2040

Year

Price
($2019/gallon)

Quantity
(billion gallons)

2026

2.50

130.88

2027

2.53

130.04

2028

2.59

129.24

2029

2.64

128.35

2030

2.76

127.59

2031

2.78

126.86

2032

2.83

126.21

2033

2.85

125.74

2034

2.89

125.40

2035

2.91

125.13

2036

2.95

124.84

2037

2.98

124.58

2038

3.02

124.37

2039

3.02

124.28

2040

3.07

124.24

Source: Energy Information Administration. Annual Energy Outlook 2021. Feb. 3, 2021.

2-20


-------
3 EMISSIONS AND ENGINEERING COSTS ANALYSIS

3.1	Introduction

In this chapter, we present estimates of the projected emissions reductions and
engineering compliance costs associated with the proposed action for the 2026 to 2040 period.
There are two main components to the analysis of emission reductions and associated
engineering compliance costs. The first component is a set of model plants for each rule,
regulated facility, and control option. Model plants are the basis for this analysis due to the large
number of affected facilities and the difficulties in conducting an analysis for each affected
facility. Characteristics of the model plants include typical equipment, operating characteristics,
and representative factors including baseline emissions and costs, emissions reductions, and
product recovery resulting from each control option. The second component is a set of
projections of activity data for affected facilities. Cost and emissions impacts are calculated by
setting parameters on how and when affected facilities are assumed to respond to a particular
regulatory regime, multiplying activity data by model plant cost and emissions estimates,
differencing from the baseline scenario, and then summing to the desired level of aggregation. In
addition to emissions reductions, some control options result in gasoline product recovery, which
can then be sold. Estimates of annualized cost include the value of the product recovery where
applicable.

3.2	Emissions Points, Controls, and Model Plants

NSPS XX, MACT R, and GACT 6B collectively regulate 4 types of facilities:

1.	Bulk Gasoline Terminals

2.	Bulk Gasoline Plants

3.	Pipeline Breakout Stations

4.	Pipeline Pumping Stations

Table 3-1 summarizes the facilities covered by each rule. Each type of facility is discussed
briefly below.

3-1


-------
Table 3-1: Regulated Facilities by Rule

Facility

NSPS XX

MACT R

GACT 6B

Bulk Gasoline Terminals

X

X

X

Bulk Gasoline Plants





X

Pipeline Breakout Stations



X

X

Pipeline Pumping Stations





X

Note: NSPS XX does not cover gasoline storage at bulk gasoline terminals

3.2.1.1 Bulk Gasoline Terminals

A bulk gasoline terminal is a gasoline storage and distribution facility that receives
gasoline by pipeline, ship, barge, or cargo tank and has a throughput of greater than 75,700 liters
per day (approximately 20,000 gallons per day). Once received at a terminal, gasoline is stored in
large storage tanks and transferred to cargo tanks via a system of equipment called a loading
rack. Once offloaded into cargo tanks, gasoline is transported from the terminal to retail gasoline
stations or intermediate storage facilities called bulk plants (discussed in the next section). Bulk
gasoline terminals are regulated by NSPS XX, MACT R, and GACT B.

3.2.1.2	Bulk Gasoline Plants

Bulk gasoline plants are like bulk gasoline terminals. They receive gasoline by pipeline,
ship, barge, or cargo tank, store the gasoline received in storage tanks, and transfer it to tanker
trucks via a loading rack. However, bulk gasoline plants handle throughput less than 20,000
gallons per day. They therefore have fewer and smaller storage tanks and smaller loading racks
than bulk gasoline terminals. Due to their smaller scale, bulk gasoline plants are area sources of
HAP and are regulated under GACT 6B.

3.2.1.3	Pipeline Breakout Stations

Pipeline breakout stations are facilities along a refined petroleum pipeline which contain
storage vessels used to relieve surges or receive and store gasoline from the pipeline for re-
injection and continued transportation by pipeline or to other facilities. Pipeline breakout stations
vary in size and emissions and are regulated by both MACT R and GACT 6B.

3.2.1.4	Pipeline Pumping Stations

Pipeline pumping stations are facilities along a pipeline containing pumps to maintain the
desired pressure and flow of product through the pipeline. They do not contain gasoline storage

3-2


-------
tanks other than surge control tanks. Pipeline pumping stations are area sources of HAP and
regulated under GACT 6B.

3,2.2 Emission Points at Regulated Facilities

This section characterizes emission points at regulated facilities and the emissions
controls evaluated by the NESHAP technology reviews and NSPS review.

3.2.2.1 Loading Racks

Gasoline stored at bulk terminals and bulk plants is pumped through metered loading
areas, or loading racks, into tanker trucks. A loading rack consists of a platform, loading arms
(which connect to the tank truck for fuel transfer), pumps, meters, valves, and piping to transfer
gasoline from the storage tank to the receiving cargo tank. The process of loading gasoline
causes displacement of gasoline vapors, which lead to VOC and HAP emissions.

The gasoline loading arm can connect to the tanker cargo tank at the top of the tank (top
loading) or the bottom of the tank (bottom loading). Top loading may occur directly through a
top loading fill pipe (splash loading) or through a connected downspout that places the entry
flow near the bottom of the tank (submerged fill). Splash loading creates turbulence that leads to
increased emissions. Bottom loading leads to submerged fill and reduced turbulence. One
method of controlling VOC emissions relative to splash loading is to use submerged fill top
loading or bottom loading.

In addition to submerged loading, emissions from loading operations can be controlled
through conveying displaced vapor through a closed vent system to a control device or fuel gas
system, and vapor balancing. The closed vent system uses piping to capture displaced vapor from
the cargo tank and route it either to a control device or to a fuel system for combustion. Vapor
balancing systems capture displaced vapor and route it through piping back to the storage tank.
Vapor balancing can only be used with fixed roof storage tanks, and thus vapor balancing is not
an option at most gasoline distribution facilities other than bulk gasoline plants (see the next
section).

This technology review MACT R and GACT 6B and the review of NSPS XX evaluated
thermal/vapor combustion units (VCUs), carbon adsorption vapor recovery units (VRUs), flares,
and refrigerated condensers based on both splash loading and submerged loading. While

3-3


-------
submerged loading is not required explicitly by current NESHAP (except for certain area source
facilities) and NSPS, it is consistent with management best-practices and is thought to be the
predominant method of loading. For this reason, it is assumed that facilities already practice
submerged loading in the baseline and all costs and emissions impacts are incremental to
submerged loading. Emissions limits at gasoline loading racks are specified in terms of allowable
emissions in milligrams of TOC per liter of gasoline loaded (mg/L).

3.2.2.2 Storage Tanks

Gasoline is stored at bulk gasoline terminals, bulk gasoline plants, and pipeline breakout
stations in large storage tanks. These storage tanks have either fixed or floating roofs. A fixed
roof tank uses a cone or dome shaped roof that is permanently affixed to the tank shell. Floating
roof tanks have a roof that sits on top of the stored gasoline and rises or falls throughout the day
based on the varying amount of gasoline stored in the tank. The floating roof of the tank may be
either external (EFR) or internal (IFR). An EFR consists of a cylindrical steel shell with a deck
that floats on the gasoline and rises and falls with the liquid level. An IFR has both a permanent
roof and a deck that floats either on the gasoline's surface or several inches above.

Most emissions from fixed roof tanks are breathing losses and emptying losses. Breathing
loss is the expulsion of vapor from a tank's vapor space that has expanded or contracted due to
changes in temperature or pressure. These losses occur without any change to the gasoline level
of the tank. Emptying loss occurs when air drawn into the tank during gasoline removal saturates
with hydrocarbon vapor and expands past the fixed capacity of the tank, overflowing through a
pressure valve. Collectively, breathing and emptying losses are called "working" losses. Fixed
roof tanks may use vents to control breathing losses and vapor balancing systems to control
emptying losses.

Gasoline storage facilities use floating-roof tanks to control working losses. A typical
EFR consists of a cylindrical steel shell with a deck that floats on the surface of the gasoline,
completely covering it except for a small gap. A seal attached to the roof slides along the shell
wall as the roof is raised and lowered. An IFR is similar but also contains a permanently affixed
roof at the top of the tank and may have a noncontact roof that floats inches above the surface of
the gasoline on pontoons. The largest source of emissions from floating roof tanks is standing-
storage loss, often caused by an improper fit between the seal and the tank shell or roof fittings.

3-4


-------
Emissions from floating roof tanks are controlled by mandating a certain type of seal and/or roof
fittings. As part of the technology review for major sources (RTI, 2021) and area sources (RTI,
2021), EPA identified a new practice for monitoring internal floating roof storage vessels using a
lower explosive limit (LEL) monitor to identify floating roofs with poor seals or fitting controls.
IFR tanks are much more common than EFR tanks. EPA estimates that approximately 95 percent
of the storage tanks in gasoline distribution are IFR tanks. Storage tanks are the largest source of
VOC emissions at gasoline distribution facilities.

Storage vessels at bulk gasoline terminals subject to NSPS XX are regulated by NSPS
subpart K, Ka, or Kb. MACT R covers all storage tanks with a capacity greater than 20,000
gallons, while NESHAP subpart 6B has primary requirements for tanks with capacity greater
than 20,000 gallons and throughput greater than 480 gallons per day or capacity greater than
40,000 gallons irrespective of throughput for bulk terminals and pipeline breakout stations. There
are no size specifications for bulk plants, but tanks smaller than 20,000 gallons are required to
have a fixed roof. For this reason, storage tanks at bulk gasoline plants have fixed roofs while
most other tanks in service in gasoline distribution have floating roofs. The technology review
and NSPS review considered a range of options for both IFR and EFR tanks, from maintaining
the minimum MACT R/GACT 6B requirements (i.e., baseline requirements) up to requiring
control beyond NSPS Kb requirements. NSPS Kb, which was promulgated in 1987, requires a
vapor-mounted primary seal, a rim-mounted secondary seal, and fitting controls for IFR tanks.
For EFR tanks, NSPS Kb requires a mechanical shoe seal with a rim-mounted secondary seal
and fitting controls.

3.2.2.3 Equipment Leaks

Equipment leaks are fugitive emissions occurring though malfunctioning valves, pumps,
hatches, or seals. Loading racks, storage vessels, and other equipment in use at bulk gasoline
terminals, bulk plants, pipeline breakout stations, and pipeline pumping stations are all potential
sources of fugitive emissions. Fugitive emissions at potential sources are controlled by leak
detection and repair (LDAR) programs. Examples of LDAR programs include audio, visual, and
olfactory (AVO) monitoring or monitoring at differing frequencies (annual or quarterly, for
example) using Method 21 or an optical gas imaging (OGI) device (instrument monitoring).
Under an LDAR regime, all components in gasoline service at a facility are inspected using the

3-5


-------
prescribed method. Under either type of regime, if leaks are detected in the normal course of
operations, they are required to be repaired. LDAR programs can vary in their emissions control
based on their frequency of monitoring (how often is equipment inspected) and efficacy of
monitoring (how likely is inspection to detect an occurring leak). Instrument monitoring will
detect leaks that cannot be detected by AVO methods.

NSPS XX equipment leak provisions apply only to vapor collection systems, vapor
processing systems, and gasoline loading racks at bulk gasoline terminals. NESHAP subpart R
and NESHAP 6B apply to all equipment in gasoline service at bulk terminals and pipeline
breakout stations and bulk terminals, bulk plants, pipeline pumping stations, and pipeline
breakout stations respectively. The technology review and NSPS review evaluated LDAR
programs ranging from the current AVO monitoring regime to periodic monitoring with Method
21 or an OGI device with monitoring frequency ranging from annual to bimonthly.

3.2.2.4 Cargo Tanks

Bulk terminals and bulk plants contain loading racks that transfer gasoline from storage
tanks into the cargo tanks of tanker trucks or railcars. Gasoline is a Class 3 flammable liquid and
may be transported using "non-pressure" cargo tanks (DOT 406) or "low-pressure" cargo tanks
(DOT 407), the requirements for which are expressed in terms of maximum allowable working
pressure (MAWP) and pressure-relief valve settings. Given the MAWP requirements for DOT
406 and DOT 407 tanks, gasoline will trigger the pressure-relief valve on DOT 406 tanks under
certain circumstances but will never trigger the pressure-relief valve on DOT 407 tanks. There
are additional legal restrictions on the transport of Class 3 flammable liquids by railcar (RTI,
2021), and railcar gasoline loading operations are not expressly included in NSPS XX. EPA
estimates less than 10 percent of gasoline is transported by railcar.

Tanks are divided into compartments with a hatchway at the top of each. Cargo tanks can
be top loaded at a loading rack by opening the hatch cover and dispensing product directly
through it. A top-loading vapor head compatible with the hatch allows vapor collection during
loading, and a better vapor-tight seal is created when top loading is performed through a top-tight
loading adapter mounted in each compartment.

3-6


-------
During bottom loading, an internal valve is opened to allow product flow, and vents
permit the exit of displaced vapor. Vapor collection systems with bottom loading equipment
collect vapors from the vents through a common manifold. The tank truck vapor-recovery line
terminates at a connector on the side or rear of the truck.

Emissions occur from cargo tanks due to vapor loss from leaking tank hatches and
pressure-relief valve venting. Controlling emissions from cargo tanks typically involves
certifying through a pressure-vacuum test that cargo tanks in use at a loading rack have a
specified degree of vapor-tightness. There is a trade-off between pressure-release emissions and
cargo tank leakage emissions as vapor-tightness requirements are tightened. For example, a tank
with a slowly leaking hatch will be less likely to trigger the pressure-relief valve. Tighter vapor
tightness standards will therefore lead to more pressure-relief events, and there is a point at
which reducing the allowed pressure drop during certification will simply shift emissions from
small leaks to emissions from increased pressure-relief valve release events; see the Technical
Memo on Loading Racks (RTI, 2021).

Given the allowed vapor-tightness standard, cargo tanks are tested and leaks are repaired
when necessary. The NESHAP technology review and NSPS review evaluated standards ranging
from maintaining the minimum vapor-tightness requirements of NSPS XX and GACT 6B to
requiring vapor-tightness to be certified to a stricter level than proposed by this action. The
allowed pressure changes by tank size examined in this RIA are in Table 3-2.

Table 3-2: Cargo Tank Vapor-Tightness Certification Standards Examined in this RIA
(inches WC)	

Cargo Tank of
Compartment Capacity
(gallons)

Current
NSPS/GACT
Standard

Current MACT
Standard

Proposed
Standard26

More Stringent
Alternative Standard3

2,500 or more

3.00

1.00

0.50

0.20

2,499 to 1,500

3.00

1.50

0.75

0.20

1,499 to 1,000

3.00

2.00

1.00

0.50

999 or less

3.00

2.50

1.25

1.00

a This more stringent standard requires allowable pressure drop limits that are less than the allowable precision of EPA Method
27. Further reductions of the vapor tightness requirements beyond those identified in the proposed standard may not be feasible in
practice.

26 The proposed standards unify the NSPS/GACT and MACT cargo tank vapor-tightness standards. The proposed
standard matches cargo tank vapor-tightness instituted by the California Air Resource Board (Title 17 CCR §
94014).

3-7


-------
3,2,3 Model Plants

As discussed in the introduction to this section, the emissions reductions and engineering
cost analyses presented in this section rely on a set of model plants. The model plant
configurations, including cost and emissions characteristics used to estimate impacts of the
proposed action, are derived from the technical analyses supporting the review of NSPS XX and
the technology review of MACT R and GACT 6B. The technical analyses consist of a set of 7
memos, referred to hereafter as the Technical Memos. The Technical Memos are included in the
docket for this proposed action and are listed in the References (Chapter 7). In the remainder of
the section, when referring to a specific technical memo, we will refer to it as the Technical
Memo on X (for example, The Technical Memo on Loading Racks to refer to the technical
analysis of emissions controls for gasoline loading racks).

The high-level model plants used in the analysis are bulk gasoline terminals, bulk
gasoline plants, pipeline breakout stations, and pipeline pumping stations. These high-level
model plants have a variety of configurations, which include specifications of model storage
tanks and loading racks present at the facility. Each type of model plant used in the analysis is
discussed below, beginning with the lower-level model plants.

3.2.3.1 Loading Racks

Gasoline transfer operations occur at bulk gasoline terminals and bulk gasoline plants.
The engineering cost analyses for NSPS XXa, MACT R, and GACT 6B each use a variety of
model bulk gasoline terminals, and the analysis for NESHAP 6B uses model bulk gasoline
plants. Each of these model plants is assigned a model loading rack, which is used to establish
baseline cost and emissions parameters and estimate how a model plant will respond to different
emissions controls for gasoline loading operations. Model loading racks are assigned to facilities
based on facility throughput. Larger loading racks have more loading arms, greater throughput
per arm, operate more days per year, and operate longer in a given day.

Model loading racks are also distinguished by their baseline emissions levels and the
control method used to achieve it. The current emissions limits vary by rule, and this is reflected
in the assignment of model loading racks to bulk plants and terminals. For example, loading
racks at major source model bulk terminals are assumed to be controlled to 10 mg/L, while

3-8


-------
loading racks at area source model large bulk terminals are assumed to be controlled to at least
80 mg/L. It is also assumed some model bulk plants and terminals are equipped with loading
racks that control emissions beyond the minimum level. Some model bulk plants are assumed to
already be using vapor balancing systems to control loading emissions, whereas some area
source model bulk terminals are assumed to exceed 80 mg/L of control by using a vapor
recovery or vapor combustion system. Further, a portion of the facilities to undergo modification
or reconstruction are assumed to be meeting either 10 mg/L, 35 mg/L, or 80 mg/L prior to
modification/reconstruction. The current standards and the regulatory options analyzed in this
RIA are discussed in Section 3.3 below. The pre-existing method and level of emissions control
at a loading rack determines the baseline cost and emissions due to loading operations at a
facility and the cost and emissions impacts of more stringent control relative to baseline. For
details on the type and distribution of model loading racks at model bulk terminals and plants,
see the Technical Memo on Loading Racks.

3.2.3.2 Storage Tanks

Gasoline storage occurs at bulk gasoline terminals, bulk gasoline plants, and pipeline
breakout stations. However, storage tanks at bulk gasoline terminals are not covered by NSPS
XX, so model storage tanks do not directly affect cost and emissions at NSPS XXa model bulk
terminals. Also, no changes to storage tank controls at bulk plants were considered in either the
proposed standards or the less and more stringent alternative standards (apart from the vapor
balancing requirement for gasoline loading operations and the filling of storage vessels).
Therefore, this discussion is only relevant to model storage tanks with floating roofs at major and
area source model bulk terminals and pipeline breakout stations.

Given the variety of tank sizes and configurations (fixed vs floating roof, internal vs
external floating roof) and current storage tank control standards, it was necessary to make
assumptions about the type and quantity of tanks present at each model bulk terminal and bulk
plant. First, bulk plants are required to used fixed roof tanks, while larger tanks at bulk terminals
and pipeline breakout stations are required to have floating roofs. Model storage tanks used in
the engineering cost analysis differ along 3 dimensions:

1. Size - 9 levels (ranging from 12,000 to 4,200,000 gallons) for IFR tanks, 7 levels
(ranging from 80,000 to 4,200,000 gallons) EFR tanks

3-9


-------
2.	Internal vs external floating roof (2 levels)

3.	Kb fitting controls included vs non-Kb compliant (2 levels)

There are 32 main model storage tank configurations, and these are distributed to model
bulk terminals and model pipeline breakout stations based on model terminal throughput and
assumptions about the underlying population of storage tanks in gasoline service. For further
details, see the Technical Memo on Storage Tanks.

3.2.3.3	Cargo Tanks

The proposed action proposes new standards for vapor-tightness of cargo trucks servicing
bulk gasoline terminals and bulk gasoline plants. To estimate the costs and emissions impacts of
these proposed standards and assign them to specific rules, there are two steps:

1.	Estimate the nationwide impacts of proposed standards based on an assumed
distribution of model cargo tanks.

2.	Assign these impacts to NSPS XXa, MACT R, and GACT 6B facilities based on
the fractional distribution of total throughput serviced by bulk terminals and
plants covered by each rule.

For example, suppose one third of gasoline throughput is assumed to occur at NSPS XXa
affected model terminals, one third is assumed to occur at MACT R affected model terminals,
and one third is assumed to occur at GACT 6B model bulk terminals and model bulk plants. In
this scenario, one third of the cost and emissions impact of each cargo tank option would be
assigned to each rule. Throughput at model bulk terminals and plants is discussed below.

For step 1, 5 model cargo tanks were used, ranging in size from 600 to 8,500-gallon tank
capacity. Each tank size had an assumed nationwide distribution, and each tank was assumed to
undergo 10 pressure-relief device releases per day. For discussion of cargo tank controls and the
assumed distribution of tanker trucks, see the Technical Memo on Loading Racks.

3.2.3.4	Pipeline Pumping Stations

There are no major source pipeline pumping stations, so all pipeline pumping stations are
covered under GACT 6B. There is only one model pipeline pumping station, so all area source
pipeline pumping stations are treated equivalently in the engineering cost analysis. For the

3-10


-------
purposes of assessing equipment leaks, each model pumping station was assumed to have 59
valves, 260 flanges and connectors, and 6 pumps.

3.2.3.5	Pipeline Breakout Stations

Pipeline breakout stations are covered by MACT R and GACT 6B. Model pipeline
breakout stations are distinguished by:

1.	Area source vs maj or source of HAP

2.	Throughput level (2 levels - 600,000 and 750,000 gpd)

3.	The number of model storage tanks (2 levels - 4 or 5). It assumed that the
600,000 gpd model breakout station uses 4 tanks, while the 750,000 gpd breakout
station uses 5 tanks.

4.	The distribution of model storage tanks between Kb and non-Kb compliant. 3
different splits between IFRT/EFRT Kb/non-Kb model storage tanks are assumed
for each rule/size combination.

This leads to 12 total configurations of model pipeline breakout stations (2 rules x 2 sizes x 3
tank configurations). For the purposes of assessing equipment leaks, each model breakout station
was assumed to have 2,980 valves, 5,230 flanges and connectors, and 75 pumps.

3.2.3.6	Bulk Gasoline Plants

Bulk gasoline plants are all area sources of HAP, so all model plants are covered by
GACT 6B for the purposes of the engineering cost analysis. Model bulk plants are all assumed to
have throughput of 15,000 gallons of gasoline per day and house two small, fixed roof storage
tanks. Model bulk plants are only distinguished by their model loading rack. A model bulk plant
may be assigned one of three possible model loading racks:

1.	A loading rack with a vapor balancing system (for both deliveries and loading)

2.	A loading rack with vapor balancing system for either deliveries or loading (but
not both)

3.	A loading rack without a vapor balancing system

3-11


-------
Model bulk plants were placed into the above three categories based on an assumed distribution
of bulk plants within states. In developing the original standards for GACT 6B (EPA, 2006),
EPA reviewed state rules to determine what states had regulations controlling emissions at bulk
plants. Certain states had rules controlling VOC emissions from loading racks or explicitly
requiring vapor-balancing systems. Based on this review, EPA estimated the proportion of bulk
plants which already had a vapor-balancing system in place due to existing state requirements.
EPA also estimated the proportion of bulk plants that would be exempt from the requirement due
to not meeting a throughput threshold of 4,000 gpd as part of this review. The engineering cost
analysis contained in this chapter thus assumes that, in the baseline, some bulk plants already
have a vapor-balancing system for either deliveries or loading (or both) and that some bulk
plants would not meet the throughput threshold required to install a vapor-balancing system. For
the distribution of bulk plants, see Table 3-5 in Section 3.2.4. For a discussion of vapor balancing
systems and the assumed distribution of loading racks at bulk plants, see the Technical Memo on
Loading Racks (RTI, 2021) and supporting documentation. For the purposes of assessing
equipment leaks, each model bulk plant was assumed to have 50 valves, 216 flanges and
connectors, and 4 pumps.

3.2.3.7 Bulk Gasoline Terminals

Each rule covers operations of bulk gasoline terminals, so there are different model bulk
gasoline terminals associated with each rule. In addition to differing by rule, model bulk
terminals differ along five dimensions:

1.	Size, determined by gasoline throughput per day and operating days per year

2.	Type of model loading rack in the baseline, based on type of control (VCU, VRU,
flare, no control) and estimated level of control (no control, 80 mg/L, 35 mg/L, 10
mg/L).

3.	Number of tanks

4.	Distribution of tanks between IFRT/EFRT and Kb/non-Kb compliant.

5.	NSPS XXa only - model plants can be new or modified/reconstructed

Between the five dimensions, there are 15 model bulk terminals used for the NSPS XXa
analysis, 9 used for the MACT R analysis, and 61 used for the GACT 6B analysis. For the

3-12


-------
purposes of assessing equipment leaks, each model bulk terminal was assumed to have 385
valves, 2,625 flanges and connectors, and 15 pumps.

3.2.4 Activity Data

The emissions reduction and engineering cost analysis presented in this chapter relies on
counts of affected facilities to support the review of NSPS XX and the technology review of
MACT R and GACT 6B. Details on these counts are contained in the underlying Technical
Memos used to support the reviews.

For NSPS XXa, 5 new and 15 modified or reconstructed bulk terminals are projected
over the first 5 years of the proposed action. To construct a count of affected facilities from
2026-2040 (See Table 3-3 below), EPA assumed the projected new and modified/reconstructed
facilities will be created uniformly over time and extrapolated the 5-year projection through 2040
(see the next section for a discussion of the analysis timeframe).

Table 3-3: NSPS XXa Projected Affected Facilities, 2026-2040

Year

New

Modified/Reconstructed

2026

4

12

2027

5

15

2028

6

18

2029

7

21

2030

8

24

2031

9

27

2032

10

30

2033

11

33

2034

12

36

2035

13

39

2036

14

42

2037

15

45

2038

16

48

2039

17

51

2040

18

54

Note: of the 15 modified/reconstructed facilities assumed by 2027,2 are assumed to be meeting an 80 mg/L loading rack
emissions limit, 5 are assumed to be meeting 35 mg/L, and 8 are assumed to be meeting 10 mg/L.

For MACT R and GACT 6B, EPA assumes the count of each affected facilities is constant
from 2026-2040. In absence of reliable data on facility closure over time, EPA considered this to
be a reasonable assumption given that gasoline consumption is projected to be roughly flat over
the projected time horizon, (EIA's AEO 2021 projects gasoline consumption will fall by 5

3-13


-------
percent from 2026 to 2040). For the distribution of high-level model plants across rules, see
Table 3-4 below.

Table 3-4: Model Plant Distribution and Configurations	



NSPS XXa



MACT R



GACT 6B

Facility Type

Count27 Configurations

Count

Configurations

Count

Configurations

Bulk Terminal

20 15

195

9

1,090

61

Bulk Plant

-

-

-

5,913

3

Pumping Station

-

-

-

1,800

1

Breakout Station

-

15

6

460

6

Throughout this chapter, various results will be presented by year for NSPS XXa but not MACT
R or GACT 6B; this is because the projection of affected facilities is only changing for NSPS
XXa.

As discussed in Section 3.2.3.6, a portion of bulk plants are assumed to either already use
a vapor balancing system of some kind or to be exempt from any vapor balancing requirement
due to not meeting a throughput threshold of 4,000 gallons per day. The distribution of model
bulk plants used for the cost and emissions analysis in this RIA is contained in Table 3-5.

Table 3-5: Assumed Distribution of Controls at Bulk Plants

Current Control

Number of Facilities

Vapor Balancing for Deliveries and Loading

1,715

Vapor Balancing for Deliveries or Loading

270

Requires Vapor Balancing

2095

Exempt Based on Low Throughput

1833

3,2,5 Baseline

The impacts of regulatory actions are evaluated relative to a baseline that represents the
world without the regulatory action. In this RIA, we present results for the proposed amendments
to NESHAP GACT 6B and MACT R and proposed NSPS XXa. Throughout this document, we
focus the analysis on the proposed requirements that result in quantifiable compliance cost or
emissions changes compared to the baseline. For each rule and most emissions sources, EPA
assumed each facility achieved emissions control meeting current standards, and estimated

27 This count reflects 5 new and 15 modified/reconstructed terminals 5 years following promulgation.

3-14


-------
emissions and cost relative to this baseline. An exception is that loading racks are assumed to use
submerged fill methods in the baseline even when not explicitly required under current NESHAP
or NSPS standards. This is discussed in Section 3.2.2.1. Further, as discussed in Section 3.2.3.6,
requirements in some states control emissions from loading racks at bulk plants. Based on a
review of state requirements applying to bulk plants, EPA estimated the proportion of these
facilities that already employ vapor-balancing systems either for dispensing gasoline, receiving
gasoline, or both. Table 3-5 in Section 3.2.4 shows the distribution of vapor-balancing systems at
bulk plants used in the analysis. Finally, with respect to cargo tank vapor-tightness standards, the
California Air Resource Board (CARB) currently requires cargo tanks be certified to the vapor-
tightness standard proposed in this action. Due to data limitations, EPA was not able to account
for the impact of the CARB cargo tank requirements in the baseline. EPA is not aware of any
other state standards that are more strict than current federal standards.

For the analysis, we calculate the cost and emissions impacts of the proposed NSPS and
NESHAP amendments from 2026 to 2040. The initial analysis year is 2026 as we assume the
proposed action will be finalized and thus become effective during 2023. We assume full
compliance with the proposed amendments to MACT R and GACT 6B will take effect three
years later in 2026, which is consistent with the requirements in Section 112 of the Clean Air Act
for HAP standards. The final analysis year is 2040, which allows us to provide fifteen years of
impacts after the proposed amendments are assumed to fully take effect. A fifteen-year timespan
was selected to cover the lifetime of the longest-lived capital equipment (upgraded storage tanks
and VRU/VCU for loading racks) expected to be installed as a result of the proposed
amendments. We assume the proposed NSPS XXa amendments take effect immediately upon
proposal (2022), which is consistent with compliance requirements for NSPS under Section 111
of the Clean Air Act. It is appropriate to set the initial analysis year as 2026 rather than 2023
given that the impacts of proposed NSPS XXa are much smaller than those for GACT 6B and
MACT R.

3.2.6 Product Recovery

Engineering cost estimates in this chapter include projections of revenue from product
recovery. This is because control options analyzed in this RIA lead to the recovery of gasoline
vapor. Recovered gasoline vapor is monetized as product recovery credits by multiplying VOC

3-15


-------
emissions reductions by a VOC credit of 480 $/ton. The VOC recovery credit was calculated
based on the average pre-tax retail price of regular conventional gasoline in 2019 ($2.50/gallon)
and assuming that 60 percent of retail price is for taxes and distribution/marketing costs28.
Therefore, EPA estimated the value of gasoline recovered to be $1.50/gallon ($2.50x0.60).

Using a density of gasoline of 6.25 lb/gallon yields the assumed VOC credit ((1.50 ($/gallon) /
6.25(lb/gallon)) x 2000(lb/ton) = 480 ($/ton)) (See the Technical Memo on Loading Racks (RTI,
2021), footnote 1). The estimated value of gasoline recovered is a conservative (lower-end)
estimate (the average rack price in 2019 was $1.82 per gallon. See Table 2-13).

Because the controls considered lead to product recovery, it is possible for the cost of a
control option to be negative once the value of product recovery is considered (the potential
annualized costs may be outweighed by the revenue from product recovery). This observation
may typically support an assumption that owners of gasoline distribution facilities would
continue to perform the emissions abatement activity regardless of whether a requirement is in
place, because it is in their private self-interest. However, there may be an opportunity cost
associated with the installation of environmental controls or implementation of compliance
activities (for purposes of mitigating the emission of pollutants) that is not reflected in the
control costs. If environmental investment displaces investment in productive capital, the
difference between the rate of return on the marginal investment displaced by the mandatory
environmental investment is a measure of the opportunity cost of the environmental requirement
to the regulated entity. To the extent that any opportunity costs are not added to the control costs,
the compliance costs presented above may be underestimated. In addition, the hurdle rate is
defined as the minimum rate of return on an investment that a firm would deem acceptable under
typical business practices. Thus, if the hurdle rate is higher on average for firms in this industry
than the interest rate used in estimating the compliance costs (in this proposed action, 3.25% at
the time of this analysis), then these investments in environmental controls may not necessarily
be undertaken on average.

From a social perspective, however, the increased financial returns from gasoline
recovery accrue to entities somewhere along the gasoline distribution supply chain and should be
accounted for in a national-level analysis. An economic argument can be made that, in the long

28 EIA, 2021. .

3-16


-------
run, no single entity bears the entire burden of compliance costs or fully appropriates the
financial gain of the additional revenues associated with gasoline recovery. The change in
economic surplus resulting from gasoline recovery is likely to be spread across different market
participants. The simplest and most transparent option for allocating these revenues would be to
assign the compliance costs and revenues to a model plant and not make assumptions regarding
the allocation of costs and revenues across agents.

3.3 Description of Regulatory Options

This RIA analyzes less and more stringent alternative regulatory options in addition to
the analyzing the amendments proposed for GACT 6B and MACT R and proposed NSPS XXa.
This section details the regulatory options examined for each rule. In addition to the control
options discussed in each section, EPA is also proposing revisions related to emissions during
periods of startup, shutdown, and malfunction (SSM); additional requirements for electronic
reporting of performance test results, performance evaluation reports, and compliance reports;
monitoring and operating requirements for control devices; and other minor technical
improvements.

3.3.1 GACT6B

GACT 6B regulates emissions from loading racks at bulk terminals and bulk plants,
storage tanks at bulk terminals, bulk plants, and pipeline breakout stations, cargo tank vapor-
tightness, and equipment leaks at bulk terminals, bulk plants, pipeline breakout stations, and
pipeline pumping stations. Under the current standards, emissions from loading racks at large
bulk gasoline terminals (those with gasoline throughput of 250,000 gallons per day or greater)
are controlled by vapor collection and processing systems meeting 80 mg/L and the cargo tanks
being loaded must be certified to be vapor tight. Small bulk gasoline terminals and bulk gasoline
plants must use submerged filling when loading gasoline. Emissions from storage vessels with a
design capacity greater than or equal to 75 m3 are controlled by equipment requirements.
Equipment leaks are repaired upon detection using AVO methods.

Based on the technology review, EPA is proposing to revise requirements for the
following:

3-17


-------
•	Loading operations: large bulk terminals must control emissions using a vapor
collection and processing system meeting 35 mg/L. Bulk plants must install
vapor-balancing systems. Cargo tanks must be certified to be vapor-tight to a
standard of 0.5" - 1.25" water pressure loss (see Table 3-2).

•	Storage Tanks: EFR tanks must have fitting controls compliant with NSPS Kb
and LEL monitoring must be conducted for IFR tanks.

•	Equipment Leaks: equipment leaks on all equipment in gasoline service at bulk
terminals, bulk plants, pipeline breakout stations, and pipeline pumping stations
must be monitored annually using EPA Method 21 or OGI.

Bulk plants that do not meet a minimum throughput threshold of 4,000 gallons per day
are exempt from the vapor balancing requirement. The current and proposed standards for GACT
6B are summarized in

Table 3-6 below.

Table 3-6: Current and Proposed Standards for NESHAP GACT 6B	

Emissions Source

Facility

Current Standard

Proposed Standard

Loading Racks

Small Bulk Terminal
(<250,000 gpd, >20,000 gpd)

Large Bulk Terminal
(>250,000 gpd)

Bulk Plant
(< 20,000 gpd)

Submerged fill

80 mg/L
Submerged fill

Submerged fill

35 mg/L

Require vapor balancing
system

Storage Tanks

Large Tanks

Compliance with NSPS Kb
except for secondary seal on
IFR tanks and some fittings
controls

Require NSPS Kb fitting
controls for EFR Tanks
and LEL monitoring for
IFR Tanks



Small Tanks

Require fixed roof tanks

Require fixed roof tanks

Equipment Leaks

Bulk Terminals, Bulk Plants,
Pipeline Breakout Stations,
Pipeline Pumping Stations

Monthly AVO inspections

Annual instrument
monitoring

Cargo Tank Vapor-
tightness

Bulk Terminals and Bulk Plants

Maximum allowable
pressure loss during
certification of 3" water
column (WC)

Maximum allowable
pressure loss during
certification of 0.5" -
1.25" WC

3-18


-------
We are also analyzing less and more stringent alternative regulatory options as compared
to our proposed option with all options being more stringent than the current GACT 6B, for this
rule in adherence to OMB Circular A-4. For GACT 6B, less stringent regulatory options include
maintaining control requirements for large storage tanks at their current level, increasing vapor-
tightness standards on cargo tanks to 1" - 2.5" water pressure loss (the current MACT
standards), and not requiring vapor-balancing systems on loading racks at bulk plants. More
stringent regulatory options include increasing equipment leak monitoring frequency from
annual to quarterly, requiring IFR tanks to meet NSPS Kb standards, and strengthening the
vapor-tightness requirement for cargo tanks. The proposed, less stringent, and more stringent
regulatory options for GACT 6B are summarized in Table 3-7 below.

Table 3-7: Regulatory Options Examined in this RIA - GACT 6B

Facility

Regulatory Option

Emissions
Source

Requirement

Less
Stringent

Proposal

More
Stringent

Bulk Terminals, Pipeline
Breakout Stations, Bulk
Plants, and Pipeline
Pumping Stations

Equipment
Leaks

Misc.

Annual Instrument
Monitoring

Quarterly Instrument
Monitoring

MRR

X

X

X

X

X
X

Bulk Terminals, Pipeline
Breakout Stations, and Bulk
Plants

Large Storage
Tanks

No change
EFR tank to Kb and
LEL Monitoring for IFR
tank

EFR tank/IFR tank to
Kb and LEL Monitoring
for IFRT

X

X

X

Bulk Terminals and Bulk
Plants

Cargo Tank
Vapor-tightness

MACT29
State Requirement
Beyond State
Requirement

X

X

X

29 With respect to cargo-tank vapor-tightness requirements, "NSPS/GACT" refers to a maximum allowable pressure
loss during certification based on current NSPS XX/GACT 6B, "MACT" refers to a maximum allowable pressure
loss during certification based on MACT R limits, "State Requirement" refers to a maximum allowable pressure
loss during certification based on the California Air Resource Board (CARB) standard, and "Beyond State
Requirement" refers to a stricter standard beyond the CARB standard. For more details, refer to the Technical
Memo on Loading Rack Control Options.

3-19


-------
Regulatory Option

Small Bulk Terminals

Loading Racks

No change

X

X

X

Large Bulk Terminals

Loading Racks

35 mg/L
10 mg/L

X

X

X

Bulk Plants

Loading Racks

No change
Vapor-balancing

X

X

X

3,3.2 MACTR

MACT R regulates emissions from loading racks and cargo tank vapor-tightness at bulk
gasoline terminals, and storage tanks and equipment leaks at bulk terminals and pipeline
breakout stations. Under the current standards, emissions from loading racks at bulk gasoline
terminals are controlled by vapor collection and processing systems meeting 10 mg/L and the
cargo tanks being loaded must be certified to be vapor tight. Emissions from storage vessels with
a design capacity greater than or equal to 75 m3 at bulk gasoline terminals and pipeline breakout
stations are controlled by equipment requirements. Equipment leaks at bulk gasoline terminals
and pipeline breakout stations are repaired upon detection using AVO methods.

Based on the technology review, EPA is proposing to revise requirements for the
following:

•	Storage Tanks: EFR tanks must have fitting controls compliant with NSPS Kb
and LEL monitoring must be conducted for IFR tanks.

•	Equipment Leaks: equipment leaks on all equipment in gasoline service at bulk
gasoline terminals and pipeline breakout stations must be monitored semiannually
using EPA Method 21 or OGI.

•	Cargo tanks must be certified to be vapor-tight to a standard of 0.5" - 1.25" water
pressure loss (see Table 3-2).

EPA is also proposing that MACT R explicitly require the use of submerged fill during loading
operations. Because submerged loading is assumed to take place in the baseline (see Section
3.2.2.1), this requirement is not expected to have direct cost or emissions implications. The
current and proposed standards for MACT R are summarized in Table 3-8 below.

3-20


-------
Table 3-8: Current and Proposed Standards for MAC ! R

Emissions Source	Facility	Current Standard	Proposed Standard

Loading Racks

Bulk Terminal

10 mg/L

No change (10 mg/L)

Storage Tanks

Bulk Terminals and Pipeline
Breakout Stations

Compliance with NSPS Kb
except for some fitting
controls

Require NSPS Kb fitting
controls for EFR Tanks
and LEL monitoring for
IFR Tanks

Equipment Leaks

Bulk Terminals and Pipeline
Breakout Stations

Monthly AVO inspections

Semiannual instrument
monitoring

Cargo Tank Vapor-tightness

Bulk Terminals

Maximum allowable
pressure loss during
certification of 1" - 2.5"
WC

Maximum allowable
pressure loss during
certification of 0.5" -
1.25" WC

We also analyze less and more stringent alternative regulatory options as compared to our

proposed option with all options being more stringent that the current MACT R, for this rule in
adherence to OMB Circular A-4. For MACT R, less stringent regulatory options include
maintaining control requirements for storage tanks at their current level, maintaining vapor-
tightness standards on cargo tanks to 1" - 2.5" water pressure loss, and implementing equipment
leak monitoring annually rather than semiannually. More stringent regulatory options include
increasing equipment leak monitoring frequency from semiannually to quarterly, requiring IFR
tanks to meet NSPS Kb standards, and strengthening the vapor-tightness requirement for cargo
tanks. The proposed, less stringent than proposed, and more stringent than proposed regulatory
options for MACT R are summarized in Table 3-9 below.

Table 3-9: Regulatory Options Examined in this RIA - MACT R	

Regulatory Option



Emissions







More

Facility

Source

Requirement

Less Stringent

Proposal

Stringent





Annual Instrument

X









Monitoring









Semiannual Instrument



X





Equipment Leaks

Monitoring









Quarterly Instrument





X





Monitoring





Bulk Terminals and Pipeline



No change

X





Breakout Stations













EFR tank to Kb and LEL



X





Storage Tanks

Monitoring for IFR tank

EFR tank/IFR tank to Kb
and LEL Monitoring for
IFRT



X



Misc.

MRR

X

X

X

3-21


-------
Regulatory Option

Loading Racks	10 mg/L	X

MACT	X

Bulk Terminals	Cargo Tank	State Requirement

Vapor-tightness	Beyond S(alc

	Requirement	

3.3.3 NSPSXXa

Proposed NSPS XXa would regulate emissions from loading racks at bulk gasoline
distribution terminals constructed or modified after date of publication of this proposed action.
Emissions from loading racks at bulk gasoline terminals are controlled by vapor collection and
processing systems meeting 35 mg/L and the cargo tanks being loaded must be certified to be
vapor tight.30 Equipment leaks are repaired upon detection using AVO methods.

Based on the NSPS review, EPA is proposing requirements for the following:

•	Loading operations: new bulk terminals must control emissions using a vapor collection
and processing system meeting 1 mg/L. Reconstructed/modified bulk terminals must
control emissions using a vapor collection and processing system meeting 10 mg/L.

Cargo tanks must be certified to be vapor-tight to a standard of 0.5" - 1.25" water
pressure loss (see Table 3-2).

•	Equipment Leaks: equipment leaks on all equipment in gasoline service at bulk gasoline
terminals must be monitored quarterly using EPA Method 21 or OGI.

The current and proposed standards for NSPS XX and NSPS XXa, respectively, are summarized
in Table 3-10 below.

Table 3-10: Current and Proposed Standards for NSPS XX and NSPS XXa	

Emissions Source

Facility

Current Standard

Proposed Standard

Loading Racks

Bulk Terminal - New

Bulk Terminal -
Modified/Reconstructed

35 mg/L
35 mg/L

1 mg/L
10 mg/L

Equipment Leaks

Bulk Terminal

Monthly AVO inspections

Quarterly instrument
monitoring

Cargo Tank Vapor-tightness

Bulk Terminal

Maximum allowable
pressure loss during
certification of 3" water
column (WC)

Maximum allowable
pressure loss during
certification of 0.5" -
1.25" WC

30 Allowance is provided to meet 80 mg/L for affected facilities with an "existing vapor processing system."

X

X

X

X

3-22


-------
We are also analyzing less and more stringent alternative regulatory options as compared to our
proposed option, but all options being more stringent that the current standard, for this rule in
adherence to OMB Circular A-4. For NSPS XXa, less stringent regulatory options increasing
vapor-tightness standards on cargo tanks to 1" - 2.5" water pressure loss (the current MACT
standards) and implementing equipment leak monitoring annually rather than quarterly. The
more stringent regulatory option includes strengthening the vapor-tightness requirement for
cargo tanks. The proposed, less stringent than proposed, and more stringent than proposed
regulatory options for NSPS XXa are summarized in Table 3-11 below.

Table 3-11: Regulatory Options Examined in this RIA - NSPS XXa

Facility

Regulatory Option

Emissions
Source

Requirement

Less More
Stringent	Proposal Stringent

Bulk Terminal

Equipment
Leaks

Loading Racks

Cargo Tank
Vapor-tightness

Misc.

Annual Instrument
Monitoring

Quarterly Instrument
Monitoring

New - 35 mg/L,
modified - 35 mg/L

New - 1 mg/L, modified
- 10 mg/L

MACT

State Requirement

Beyond State
Requirement

MRR

X

X

X

X

X

X

X

X

X

X

X
X

3.4 Emissions Reduction Analysis

3.4.1 Baseline VOC/HAPEmissions Estimates

The baseline emissions for VOC and HAP (tons per year) are contained in Table 3-12
below. Recall from Section 3.2.4 that the projected count of affected facilities for MACT R and
GACT 6B is constant from 2026-2040, while projected facility counts for NSPS XXa are
projected to vary over time. Baseline emissions are thus constant for MACT R and GACT 6B
but variable for NSPS XXa. The figures for NSPS XXa in Table 3-12 reflect baseline emissions
in 2027, 5 years following the promulgation of the rule. This caveat applies to all per-year

3-23


-------
figures presented for NSPS XXa for the remainder of the chapter. Baseline emissions for NSPS
XXa from 2026-2040 are in Table 3-13.

Table 3-12: Baseline Emissions in 2027 (Short Tons)

Rule

VOC Baseline Emissions

HAP Baseline Emissions

NSPS XXa

3,900

160

MACTR

18,000

850

GACT 6B

99,000

5,300

All

120,000

6,300

Note: Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise noted.



Table 3-13: NSPS XXa Baseline Emissions (Tons), 2026-2040



Year

VOC Baseline Emissions

HAP Baseline Emissions

2026

3,100

120

2027

3,900

160

2028

4,700

190

2029

5,400

220

2030

6,200

250

2031

7,000

280

2032

7,800

310

2033

8,600

340

2034

9,300

370

2035

10,000

400

2036

11,000

440

2037

12,000

470

2038

12,000

500

2039

13,000

530

2040

14,000

560

Note: Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise noted.

3,4.2 Projected VOC/HAPEmissions Reduction

Projected emissions reductions for each rule and option package are presented in Table
3-14 below. Reductions for every year from 2026-2040 are presented for NSPS XXa in Table
3-15. Roughly 89 percent of the VOC emissions reductions and 91 percent of the HAP emissions
reductions projected under the proposed options are due to the revisions affecting GACT 6B.
The same is broadly true for the less stringent (92 percent and 94 percent) and more stringent (91
percent and 90 percent) alternative regulatory options. Further, the bulk of the VOC/HAP
emissions reductions projected under GACT 6B are coming from the requirement that bulk
plants install a vapor-balancing system to control emissions from loading operations (24,000 tons

3-24


-------
of projected VOC reductions per year, 950 tons of projected HAP reductions per year). For a
discussion of emissions reduction by emissions point for each rule and option package, see
Section 3.5.1 below.

3-25


-------
Table 3-14: Emissions Reductions for Regulatory Options, Tons per Year

Rule

Option Package

voc

HAP



Less Stringent

240

12

NSPS XXa

Proposed

2,900

120



More Stringent

3,000

120



Less Stringent

0

0

MACTR

Proposed

2,200

130



More Stringent

2,700

160



Less Stringent

11,000

890

GACT 6B

Proposed

40,000

2,100



More Stringent

50,000

2,700



Less Stringent

12,000

950

All Rules

Recommended

45,000

2,300



More Stringent

56,000

3,000

Note: Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise noted.

Note: NSPS XXa reductions reflect those occurring in 2027. For each year 2026-2040, see Table 3-15 below.
Note: The options whose emission reductions are included in this table for each rule are those described in Tables
3-7, 3-9, and 3-11.

Table 3-15: Emissions Reductions for Regulatory Options (Tons), NSPS XXa, 2026-2040

Year

Less Stringent

Proposed



More Stringent



VOC

HAP

VOC

HAP

VOC

HAP

2026

200

10

2,400

97

2,400

98

2027

240

12

2,900

120

3,000

120

2028

290

14

3,500

150

3,600

150

2029

340

17

4,100

170

4,100

170

2030

390

19

4,700

190

4,700

200

2031

440

22

5,300

220

5,300

220

2032

490

24

5,900

240

5,900

240

2033

540

26

6,500

270

6,500

270

2034

590

29

7,100

290

7,100

290

2035

640

31

7,700

320

7,700

320

2036

680

34

8,200

340

8,300

340

2037

730

36

8,800

370

8,900

370

2038

780

38

9,400

390

9,500

390

2039

830

41

10,000

410

10,000

420

2040

880

43

11,000

440

11,000

440

Note: Totals may not sum due to independent rounding. Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise

noted.

3.4.3 Projected Secondary Emissions Increases

With the additional operation of control devices associated with the proposed action,
CO2, NOx, SO2, and CO emissions will be generated as a result of the additional electricity and
natural gas usage required to operate them. All secondary emissions impacts are associated with

3-26


-------
the usage of vapor combustion and recovery units on loading racks at bulk gasoline terminals.
Because no amendments are being proposed for loading racks at major source bulk terminals in
either the proposed, less stringent, or more stringent alternative options, no secondary emissions
increases are projected for MACT R. This section characterizes the projected increases of CO2,
NOx, SO2, and CO caused by the action.

Table 3-16 and Table 3-17 contain the projected secondary emissions increases
associated with the proposed, less stringent, and more stringent options for GACT 6B and NSPS
XXa. The more stringent alternative options for GACT 6B contain stricter emissions limits for
loading racks at large bulk terminals, causing slight increases in projected secondary impacts.
The proposed, less stringent, and more stringent alternative options for NSPS contain the same
standards for loading racks, so secondary impacts are the same across the three option packages.

Table 3-16: GACT 6B Secondary Emissions Increases (short tons)

Proposed/Less Stringent Options

More Stringent Options



C02

N02

S02

CO

C02

N02

S02

CO

Per-Year

32,000

19

0.04

86

33,000

19

0.23

86

2026-2040

490,000

280

0.64

1,300

490,000

290

3.5

1,300

Note: Totals may not sum due to independent rounding. Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise noted.

Table 3-17: NSPS XXa Secondary Emissions Increases, Proposed/Less Stringent/More
Stringent Options (Tons)	

Year

C02

N02

S02

CO

2026

1,800

1.2

1.0

0

2027

2,200

1.5

1.3

0

2028

2,700

1.8

1.5

0

2029

3,100

2.1

1.8

0

2030

3,600

2.4

2.0

0

2031

4,000

2.7

2.3

0

2032

4,500

3.0

2.5

0

2033

4,900

3.3

2.8

0

2034

5,400

3.6

3.0

0

2035

5,800

3.9

3.3

0

2036

6,200

4.2

3.5

0

2037

6,700

4.5

3.8

0

2038

7,100

4.8

4.0

0

2039

7,600

5.1

4.3

0

2040

8,000

5.4

4.5

0

Total

74,000

50

42

0

Note: Totals may not sum due to independent rounding. Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise noted.

3-27


-------
3.5 Engineering Cost Analysis

3,5,1 Detailed Impacts Tables

This section presents detailed impacts tables by rule and option package. All tables
contain per-year figures other than tables representing NSPS XXa, which contains figures for the
representative year 2027 (five years following expected promulgation). Total annualized costs
include capital cost annualized using the bank prime rate in accord with the guidance of the EPA
Air Pollution Control Cost Manual (EPA, 2017a), operating and maintenance costs, and product
recovery (recovered gasoline). To estimate these annualized costs, the EPA uses a conventional
and widely accepted approach, called equivalent uniform annual cost (EUAC) that applies a
capital recovery factor (CRF) multiplier to capital investments and adds that to the annual
incremental operating expenses to estimate annual costs. This cost estimation approach is
described in the EPA Air Pollution Control Cost Manual (EPA, 2017a). These annualized costs
are the costs to directly affected firms and facilities (or "private investment"), and thus are not
true social costs. Detailed discussion of these costs can be found in the technical memos
produced for each proposed rule that can be found in the docket. Product recovery (gasoline)
estimates by emissions point is shown below, and the concept of product recovery is discussed
earlier in Section 3.2.6. The bank prime rate was 3.25 percent at the time of the analysis but has
since risen to 3.5%. All cost figures are in 2019$.

3.5.1.1 GACT6B

Table 3-18 contains per-year impacts by emissions point for the proposed amendments to
GACT 6B.

Table 3-18: Proposed Options, Detailed Impacts by Emissions Point (per year), GACT 6B

Emissions Point

Total Annualized

Cost without
Product Recovery

Product Recovery

Total
Annualized
Cost with
Product
Recovery

voc

Reductions

HAP
Reductions

Loading Racks

$7,500,000

$11,000,000

-$3,900,000

25,000

980

Storage Tanks

$1,200,000

$1,800,000

-$570,000

3,800

190

Equipment Leaks

-$4,200,000

$3,500,000

-$7,700,000

7,300

730

3-28


-------
Cargo Tanks	$1,100,000	$2,300,000	-$1,200,000 4,700	190

MRR	$7,500,000	$0	$7,500,000	0	0

Total	$13,000,000	$19,000,000	-$5,900,000 40,000 2,100

Note: Totals may not sum due to independent rounding. Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise
noted. Negative signs denote cost savings (product recovery exceeding compliance costs).

The driver of impacts from these amendments is the vapor balancing requirement for loading
racks at bulk plants, which accounts for about 95 percent of the annualized costs associated with
loading racks and about 97 percent of the emissions reductions. Loading racks in total account
for about 62 percent of the VOC reductions from the proposed amendments to GACT 6B, with
the remainder coming from storage tanks, equipment leaks, and cargo tanks in roughly equal
measure. The second largest component of annualized cost is those resulting from the updates to
Monitoring, Reporting, and Recordkeeping (MRR). These MRR updates include additional
monitoring of flares and thermal combustion units at loading racks, periodic testing of thermal
combustion units at loading racks, and annual LEL (lower explosive level) monitoring at storage
vessels as listed in the monitoring options and costs memo prepared for this proposed action
(RTI, 2022).

Note that annual instrument monitoring for equipment leaks is cost-saving relative to the
current requirement of monthly AVO monitoring. This is due to the cost savings realized by
reducing monitoring frequency from monthly to annual. Despite instrument monitoring (by
either OGI or Method 21) being more costly per monitoring event (and in the case of OGI
requiring capital usage). As monitoring frequency increases, instrument monitoring is less likely
to be cost-saving relative to current AVO. See the Technical Memo on Equipment Leaks (RTI,
2021) for details of the analysis.

Table 3-19: Less Stringent Options, Detailed Impacts by Emissions Point (per year), GACT
6B	

Total Annualized	Total Annualized yoc	HAP

Emissions Point Cost without Product Product Recovery Cost with Product	, .

„ „ Reductions Reductions
	Recovery	Recovery	

Loading Racks	$380,000	$66,000	$320,000	820	33

Storage Tanks $0	$0	$0	0	0

Equipment Leaks	-$4,200,000	$3,500,000	-$7,700,000	7,300	730

Cargo Tanks	$600,000	$1,600,000	-$1,000,000	3,300	130

MRR	$5,900,000	$0	$5,900,000	0	0

3-29


-------
Total	$2,700,000	$5,200,000	-$2,500,000	11,000	890

Note: Totals may not sum due to independent rounding. Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise
noted. Negative signs denote cost savings (product recovery exceeding compliance costs, or savings without product
recovery). Options described in Table 3-7.

Table 3-19 contains per-year impacts by emissions point for the less stringent alternative
options for GACT 6B. The main difference from the proposed options is removal of the
requirement for vapor-balancing systems at bulk plants, which substantially reduces annualized
cost and emissions reductions. MRR is by far the largest component of cost for the less stringent
alternative option package.

Table 3-20: More Stringent Options, Detailed Impacts by Emissions Point (per year),
GACT 6B

Emissions Point

Total
Annualized
Cost without
Product
Recovery

Product Recovery

Total
Annualized
Cost with
Product
Recovery

voc

Reductions

HAP
Reductions

Loading Racks

$10,000,000

$12,000,000

-$1,600,000

27,000

1,100

Storage Tanks

$20,000,000

$3,700,000

$16,000,000

7,700

380

Equipment Leaks

$10,000,000

$5,200,000

$4,900,000

11,000

1,100

Cargo Tanks

$1,500,000

$2,400,000

-$850,000

5,000

200

MRR

$7,500,000

$0

$7,500,000

0

0

Total

$49,000,000

$23,000,000

$26,000,000

50,000

2,700

Note: Totals may not sum due to independent rounding. Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise
noted. Negative signs denote cost savings (product recovery exceeding compliance costs). Options are summarized
in Table 3-11.

Table 3-20 contains per-year impacts by emissions point for the more stringent
alternative options for GACT 6B. The more stringent alternative options tighten requirements at
every emissions point (excluding MRR). The main driver of emissions reductions continues to be
the loading rack requirement, which accounts for more than half of emissions reductions. The
requirement for IFR tanks to meet NSPS Kb standards results in a major increase in annualized
costs with a comparatively small increase in emissions reductions. Tightening standards for IFR
tanks is substantially more costly than for EFR tanks because most of the tanks at gasoline
distribution facilities are IFR tanks. Further, per-tank emissions reductions are much lower when
upgrading an IFR tank to Kb relative to an EFR tank. One result of having IFR tanks meet NSPS
Kb standards is that the costs of equipment leak controls exceeds that of the product recovery
that would occur as a result of these controls, hence yielding a positive annualized cost as a
whole.

3-30


-------
3.5.1.2 MACTR

Table 3-21 contains per-year impacts by emissions point for the proposed amendments to
MACT R, which tighten requirements for storage tanks, equipment leak monitoring, cargo tank
vapor-tightness, and MRR.

Table 3-21: Proposed Options, Detailed Impacts by Emissions Point (per year), MACT R

Emissions Point

Total Annualized
Cost without Product
Recovery

Product Recovery

Total
Annualized
Cost with
Product
Recovery

voc

Reductions

HAP
Reductions

Loading Racks

$0

$0

$0

0

0

Storage Tanks

$230,000

$300,000

-$72,000

630

31

Equipment Leaks

-$48,000

$330,000

-$380,000

690

69

Cargo Tanks

$640,000

$410,000

$240,000

850

34

MRR

$2,300,000

$0

$2,300,000

0

0

Total

$3,100,000

$1,000,000

$2,100,000

2,200

130

Note: Totals may not sum due to independent rounding. Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise
noted. Negative signs denote cost savings (product recovery exceeding compliance costs, or savings in costs without
product recovery).

The majority of the annualized costs come from increased MRR requirements, and emissions
reductions are small compared to those for GACT 6B due to the smaller number of major source
facilities. Note that, as with GACT 6B, annual instrument monitoring for equipment leaks is
projected to be cost-saving relative to the current monthly AVO inspection requirement due to
cost savings from reduced monitoring frequency.

Table 3-22: Less Stringent Options, Detailed Impacts by Emissions Point (per year),
MACTR

Emissions Point

Total Annualized
Cost without Product
Recovery

Product Recovery

Total
Annualized
Cost with
Product
Recovery

VOC
Reductions

HAP
Reductions

Loading Racks

$0

$0

$0

0

0

Storage Tanks

$0

$0

$0

0

0

Equipment Leaks

-$380,000

$220,000

-$600,000

460

46

Cargo Tanks

$360,000

$0

$360,000

0

0

MRR

$2,300,000

$0

$2,300,000

0

0

Total

$2,300,000

$220,000

$2,100,000

460

46

3-31


-------
Note: Totals may not sum due to independent rounding. Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise
noted. Negative signs denote cost savings (product recovery exceeding compliance costs, or savings in costs without
product recovery).

Table 3-22 contains per-year impacts by emissions point for the less stringent alternative
options for MACT R. The less stringent set of alternative options maintains storage tank and
cargo tank vapor tightness requirements at their current level and reduces the frequency of
equipment leak monitoring. All emissions reductions come from leak detection and repair, and
the bulk of the costs once again come from increased MRR.

Table 3-23: More Stringent Options, Detailed Impacts by Emissions Point (per year),
MACT R

Emissions Point

Total Annualized

Cost without
Product Recovery

Product Recovery

Total
Annualized
Cost with
Product
Recovery

voc

Reductions

HAP
Reductions

Loading Racks

$0

$0

$0

0

0

Storage Tanks

$4,300,000

$410,000

$3,900,000

850

42

Equipment Leaks

$560,000

$390,000

$170,000

820

82

Cargo Tanks

$940,000

$490,000

$450,000

1,000

41

MRR

$2,300,000

$0

$2,300,000

0

0

Total

$8,100,000

$1,300,000

$6,800,000

$2,700

$170

Note: Totals may not sum due to independent rounding. Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise
noted.

Table 3-23 contains per-year impacts by emissions point for the more stringent
alternative options for MACT R. As with the more stringent alternative options for GACT 6B,
the requirement for IFR tanks to meet NSPS Kb standards increases costs dramatically while
only marginally reducing emissions. Increased equipment leak monitoring frequency and stricter
vapor-tightness requirements for cargo tanks lead to small increases in cost and emissions
reductions.

3.5.1.3 NSPSXXa

Table 3-24 contains impacts by emissions point for the proposed NSPS XXa in 2027,
assuming 5 new and 15 modified/reconstructed facilities 5 years following promulgation.

3-32


-------
Table 3-24: Proposed Options, Detailed Impacts by Emissions Point (2027), NSPS XXa

Emissions Point

Total
Annualized Cost
without Product
Recovery

Product Recovery

Total
Annualized
Cost with
Product
Recovery

voc

Reductions

HAP
Reductions

Loading Racks

$1,400,000

$1,200,000

$210,000

2,600

100

Equipment Leaks

$48,000

$31,000

$17,000

65

7

Cargo Tanks

$66,000

$140,000

-$75,000

290

12

MRR

$240,000

$0

$240,000

0

0

Total

$1,800,000

$1,400,000

$390,000

2,900

120

Note: Totals may not sum due to independent rounding. Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise
noted. Negative signs denote cost savings (product recovery exceeding compliance costs, or savings in costs without
product recovery).

The majority of annualized cost and emissions reductions result from tight emissions limits on
loading racks. Both costs and emissions overall are relatively small for the proposed NSPS XXa.

Table 3-25: Less Stringent Options, Detailed Impacts by Emissions Point (2027), NSPS
XXa

Emissions Point

Total
Annualized Cost
without Product
Recovery

Product Recovery

Total
Annualized
Cost with
Product
Recovery

VOC
Reductions

HAP
Reductions

Loading Racks

$0

$0

$0

0

0

Equipment Leaks

-$25,000

$18,000

-$42,000

37

4

Cargo Tanks

$37,000

$100,000

-$62,000

210

8

MRR

$240,000

$0

$240,000

0

0

Total

$250,000

$120,000

$130,000

240

12

Note: Totals may not sum due to independent rounding. Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise
noted. Negative signs denote cost savings (product recovery exceeding compliance costs, or savings in costs
without product recovery).

Table 3-25 contains impacts by emissions point for the less stringent alternative options
for NSPS XXa in 2027, assuming 5 new and 15 modified/reconstructed facilities 5 years
following promulgation. The less stringent alternative options for NSPS XXa maintain loading
emissions at their current level, and thus eliminated most of the cost and emissions reductions.
Equipment leak monitoring frequency is reduced, and cargo tank vapor-tightness requirements
are also loosened relative to the proposed options, marginally impacting cost and emissions
reductions.

3-33


-------
Table 3-26: More Stringent Options, Detailed Impacts by Emissions Point (2028), NSPS
XXa

Emissions Point

Total
Annualized Cost
without Product
Recovery

Product Recovery

Total
Annualized
Cost with
Product
Recovery

voc

Reductions

HAP
Reductions

Loading Racks

$1,400,000

$1,200,000

$210,000

2,600

100

Equipment Leaks

$48,000

$31,000

$17,000

65

7

Cargo Tanks

$97,000

$150,000

-$53,000

310

13

MRR

$240,000

$0

$240,000

0

0

Total

$1,800,000

$1,400,000

$410,000

3,000

120

Note: Totals may not sum due to independent rounding. Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise
noted. Negative signs denote cost savings (product recovery exceeding compliance costs, or savings in costs
without product recovery).

Table 3-26 contains impacts by emissions point for the more stringent alternative options
for NSPS XXa in 2028, assuming 5 new and 15 modified/reconstructed facilities 5 years
following promulgation. The more stringent alternative differs from the proposed options only
by adopting a stricter cargo tank vapor-tightness requirement, cost and emissions are virtually
identical under the two options.

3,5,2 Summary Cost Tables

Estimates of costs per year for each rule and regulatory option are presented below in
Table 3-27. The "Capital Cost" column reflects the per-year capital cost for a rule/regulatory
option assuming that the cost for each piece of capital is distributed evenly over the life of the
equipment applied in the cost estimate for that option. The even distribution of capital cost is an
outcome of the Equivalent Uniform Annual Cost (EUAC) method that, as mentioned earlier in
this RIA, is a cost methodology employed to estimate the compliance costs for this proposed
rulemaking. The "One-Time Capital Cost" (also called the Total Capital Investment) assumes
that all capital required for compliance with a rule/regulatory option is purchased in a single
year. Total annualized costs are reported both with and without revenue from product recovery
included. See Section 3.2.6 for a discussion of product recovery.

3-34


-------
Table 3-27: Estimated Annual Costs for Regulatory Options

Rule

Option Package

One-Time
Capital Cost

Annual Capital
Cost

Operation and
Maintenance

Total
Annualized Cost
w/o Revenue

Revenue from
Product
Recovery

Total
Annualized Cost
w/ Revenue



Less Stringent

$20,000

$3,200

$200,000

$250,000

$120,000

$130,000

NSPS XXa

Proposed

$7,200,000

$390,000

$950,000

$1,800,000

$1,400,000

$390,000



More Stringent

$7,200,000

$390,000

$970,000

$1,800,000

$1,400,000

$410,000



Less Stringent

$220,000

$44,000

$2,300,000

$2,300,000

$220,000

$2,100,000

MACTR

Proposed

$2,100,000

$170,000

$2,900,000

$3,100,000

$1,000,000

$2,100,000



More Stringent

$45,000,000

$3,100,000

$3,800,000

$8,000,000

$1,300,000

$6,800,000



Less Stringent

$5,800,000

$1,200,000

$1,400,000

$2,700,000

$5,200,000

-$2,500,000

GACT 6B

Proposed

$58,000,000

$6,000,000

$5,900,000

$13,000,000

$19,000,000

-$5,900,000



More Stringent

$260,000,000

$20,000,000

$23,000,000

$49,000,000

$23,000,000

$26,000,000



Less Stringent

$6,000,000

$1,200,000

$3,900,000

$5,200,000

$5,500,000

-$250,000

Total

Proposed

$67,000,000

$6,700,000

$10,000,000

$18,000,000

$21,000,000

-$3,400,000



More Stringent

$320,000,000

$23,000,000

$28,000,000

$59,000,000

$26,000,000

$33,000,000

Note: Totals may not sum due to independent rounding. Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise noted. Negative signs denote cost savings
(product recovery exceeding compliance costs, or savings in costs without product recovery). The one-time capital cost is the total capital investment as defined
in the US EPA Air Pollution Control Cost Manual (EPA, 2017a). Annual capital cost is the capital recovery costs for each option. All costs are in 2019 dollars.

3-35


-------
Table 3-28: Present and Equivalent Annual Values of Compliance Costs of Regulatory Options, 2026-2040 (million 2019$,
discounted to 2022)	







3 Percent



7 Percent

Rule

Option Package

Compliance Cost

Product Recovery

Compliance Cost

Product Recovery





PV

EAV

PV

EAV

PV

EAV

PV

EAV



Less Stringent

$5.7

$0.5

$2.7

$0.2

$3.6

$0.4

$1.7

$0.2

NSPS XXa

Proposed

$41

$3.4

$32

$2.7

$26

$2.9

$21

$2.3



More Stringent

$42

$3.5

$32

$2.7

$27

$2.9

$21

$2.3



Less Stringent

$25

$2.1

$2.4

$0.2

$17

$1.9

$1.6

$0.2

MACTR

Proposed

$34

$2.9

$11

$1.0

$23

$2.6

$7.7

$0.9



More Stringent

$88

$7.4

$14

$1.2

$60

$6.6

$9.6

$1.1



Less Stringent

$29

$2.5

$56

$4.7

$20

$2.2

$38

$4.2

GACT 6B

Proposed

$140

$12

$210

$17

$98

$11

$140

$16



More Stringent

$540

$45

$250

$21

$370

$40

$170

$19



Less Stringent

$60

$5.0

$61

$5.1

$41

$4.5

$42

$4.6

Total

Proposed

$220

$18

$250

$21

$150

$16

$170

$19



More Stringent

$670

$56

$300

$25

$450

$50

$200

$22

Note: Totals may not sum due to independent rounding. Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise noted.

3-36


-------
As shown in Table 3-28, most of the projected cost of the proposed action comes from the
proposed amendments to GACT 6B. This includes 95 percent of the capital cost, 65 percent of
the operation and maintenance cost, 87 percent of the one-time capital cost, and 72 percent of the
total annualized cost without including revenue from product recovery. GACT 6B also accounts
for the bulk of estimated revenue from product recovery (90 percent).

Table 3-28 includes the present value and equivalent annualized value of compliance cost
and revenue for the period 2026 to 2040, discounted to 2022 using social discount rates of 3
percent and 7 percent to adhere to OMB guidance in Circular A-4 for regulatory analysis. The
present value of the projected compliance cost associated with the proposed action is $150
million using a 7 percent social discount rate ($220 million using a 3 percent discount rate). Of
these totals, roughly 2/3 can be attributed to GACT 6B and 1/6 to each of MACT R and NSPS
XXa. The value of product recovery is projected to be substantial, outweighing the projecting
compliance costs of the action across the three rules. About 87.5 percent of this value comes
from the amendments to GACT 6B, approximately in line with its share of VOC emissions
reductions.

Discounted costs and revenue from product recovery for the proposed options presented
cumulatively for the three rules from 2026 to 2040 are contained in Table 3-29 and Table 3-30.
For equivalent tables for each individual rule, see Appendix B.

3-37


-------
Table 3-29: Discounted Capital and O&M Costs, Proposed Options, for NSPS XXa, MACT R, and GACT 6B, 2026-2040
(million 2019$, discounted to 2022)	

3 percent	7 percent

Year

Capital Cost

Operating and
Maintenance
Cost

Revenue from
Product
Recovery

Total
Annualized
Cost with
Revenue from
Product
Recovery

Capital Cost

Operating and
Maintenance
Cost

Revenue from
Product
Recovery

Total
Annualized
Cost with
Revenue from
Product
Recovery

2026

$5.8

$8.7

$19

($4.3)

$5.0

$7.5

$16

($4)

2027

$5.7

$8.7

$19

($4.1)

$4.8

$7.2

$15

($3)

2028

$5.7

$8.6

$18

($3.9)

$4.5

$6.9

$14

($3)

2029

$5.6

$8.6

$18

($3.8)

$4.3

$6.6

$14

($3)

2030

$5.5

$8.5

$18

($3.6)

$4.0

$6.3

$13

($3)

2031

$5.4

$8.4

$17

($3.5)

$3.8

$6.0

$12

($3)

2032

$5.3

$8.4

$17

($3.4)

$3.6

$5.7

$12

($2)

2033

$5.2

$8.3

$17

($3.2)

$3.4

$5.5

$11

($2)

2034

$5.1

$8.2

$16

($3.1)

$3.3

$5.2

$10

($2)

2035

$5.1

$8.1

$16

($3.0)

$3.1

$5.0

$10

($2)

2036

$5.0

$8.1

$16

($2.8)

$2.9

$4.7

$9

($2)

2037

$4.9

$8.0

$16

($2.7)

$2.8

$4.5

$9

($2)

2038

$4.8

$7.9

$15

($2.6)

$2.6

$4.3

$8

($1)

2039

$4.7

$7.8

$15

($2.5)

$2.5

$4.1

$8

($1)

2040

$4.7

$7.7

$15

($2.4)

$2.3

$3.9

$7

($1)

Note: Discounted to 2022. Totals may not sum due to independent rounding. Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise noted. Negative signs denote cost savings
(product recovery exceeding compliance costs).

3-38


-------
Table 3-30: Discounted Costs, Proposed Options, for NSPS XXa, MACT R, and GACT 6B, 2026-2040 (million 2019$,
discounted to 2022)	

3 percent

7 percent



Annualized Costs

Revenue from Product

Annualized Costs (with

Annualized Costs

Revenue from

Annualized Costs

Year

(w/o Revenue)

Recovery

Revenue)

(w/o Revenue)

Product Recovery

(with Revenue)

2026

$16

$19

($3.1)

$14

$16

($2.7)

2027

$16

$19

($2.9)

$13

$15

($2.4)

2028

$15

$18

($2.8)

$12

$14

($2.2)

2029

$15

$18

($2.7)

$12

$14

($2.0)

2030

$15

$18

($2.5)

$11

$13

($1.9)

2031

$15

$17

($2.4)

$11

$12

($1.7)

2032

$15

$17

($2.3)

$10

$12

($1.5)

2033

$15

$17

($2.1)

$9.6

$11

($1.4)

2034

$14

$16

($2.0)

$9.1

$10

($1.3)

2035

$14

$16

($1.9)

$8.7

$10

($1.2)

2036

$14

$16

($1.8)

$8.3

$9.3

($1.1)

2037

$14

$16

($1.7)

$7.9

$8.8

($1.0)

2038

$14

$15

($1.6)

$7.5

$8.3

($0.9)

2039

$14

$15

($1.5)

$7.1

$7.9

($0.8)

2040

$13

$15

($1.4)

$6.7

$7.4

($0.7)

Note: Discounted to 2022. Totals may not sum due to independent rounding. Numbers rounded to two significant digits unless otherwise noted. Negative signs denote cost savings
(product recovery exceeding compliance costs, or savings in costs without product recovery).

3-39


-------
4 HUMAN HEALTH BENEFITS OF EMISSIONS REDUCTIONS

4.1	Introduction

The emission controls installed to comply with this proposed action are expected to
reduce emissions of volatile organic compounds (VOC) which, in conjunction with NOx and in
the presence of sunlight, form ground-level ozone (O3). This chapter reports the estimated ozone-
related benefits of reducing VOC emissions in terms of the number and value of avoided ozone-
attributable deaths and illnesses. The potential benefits from reduced ecosystem effects from the
reduction in O3 concentrations are not quantified or monetized here. Time and data limitations
for quantifying the effect of this action on biomass loss and foliar injury and the ensuing loss of
ecosystem services prevent an assessment of the benefits to ecosystems. The EPA provides a
qualitative discussion of the benefits of reducing HAP emissions later in this chapter. This
discussion can also be found in section 4.7 of the promulgated Affordable Clean Energy (ACE)
rule (U.S. EPA, 2019). Finally, we include an analysis of the climate disbenefits for this
proposed action.

The PV of the cumulative monetized health benefits for the recommended options for all
3 proposed rules are $1,800 million long-term at the 3 percent discount rate to $1,100 million at
the 7 percent discount rate for the benefits with an EAV of $150 million to $120 million,
respectively. Specific estimates of monetized health estimates for each proposed rule can be
found later in this chapter in section 4.7. All estimates are reported in 2019 dollars. The
monetized climate disbenefits resulting from increasing emissions of CO2 as presented in
Chapter 3 are included in this chapter in Section 4.6. The monetized climate disbenefits reflect
interim global benefit per ton estimates as explained later in this RIA chapter, are estimated at
$32 million PV at a 3 percent discount rate ($2.7 million EAV).

4.2	VOC-related Human Health Benefits

This section summarizes the EPA's approach to estimating the incidence and economic
value of the ozone-related benefits estimated for this action. The Regulatory Impact Analysis
(RIA) Final Revised Cross-State Air Pollution Rule (U.S. EPA, 2021) and its corresponding
Technical Support Document Estimating PM2.5 -and Ozone - Attributable Health Benefits (TSD)
(U.S. EPA, 2021) provide a full discussion of the EPA's approach for quantifying the incidence

4-1


-------
and value of estimated air pollution-related health impacts. In these documents, the reader can
find the rationale for selecting the health endpoints quantified; the demographic, health and
economic data applied in the environmental Benefits Mapping and Analysis Program—
Community Edition (BenMAP-CE); modeling assumptions; and the EPA's techniques for
quantifying uncertainty.

Implementing this action will affect the distribution of ozone concentrations throughout
the U.S.; this includes locations both meeting and exceeding the NAAQS for O3. This RIA
estimates avoided Cb-related health impacts that are distinct from those reported in the RIAs for
the O3 NAAQS (U.S. EPA, 2015). The O3 NAAQS RIAs hypothesize, but do not predict, the
benefits and costs of strategies that States may choose to enact when implementing a revised
NAAQS; these costs and benefits are illustrative and cannot be added to the costs and benefits of
policies that prescribe specific emission control measures.

4,2,1 Estimating Ozone Related Health Impacts

We estimate the quantity and economic value of air pollution-related effects by
estimating counts of air pollution-attributable cases of adverse health outcomes, assigning dollar
values to these counts, and assuming that each outcome is independent of one another. We
construct these estimates by adapting primary research—specifically, air pollution epidemiology
studies and economic value studies—from similar contexts. This approach is sometimes referred
to as "benefits transfer." Below we describe the procedure we follow for: (1) selecting air
pollution health endpoints to quantify; (2) calculating counts of air pollution effects using a
health impact function; (3) specifying the health impact function with concentration-response
parameters drawn from the epidemiological literature.

4.2.1.1 Selecting air pollution health endpoints to quantify

As a first step in quantifying Cb-related human health impacts, the EPA consults the
Integrated Science Assessment for Ozone (Ozone ISA) (U.S. EPA, 2020) as summarized in the
TSD for the Final Revised Cross State Air Pollution Rule Update (U.S. EPA, 2021). This
document synthesizes the toxicological, clinical, and epidemiological evidence to determine
whether each pollutant is causally related to an array of adverse human health outcomes
associated with either acute (i.e., hours or days-long) or chronic (i.e., years-long) exposure. For

4-2


-------
each outcome, the ISA reports this relationship to be causal, likely to be causal, suggestive of a
causal relationship, inadequate to infer a causal relationship, or not likely to be a causal
relationship.

In brief, the ISA for ozone found short-term (less than one month) exposures to ozone to
be causally related to respiratory effects, a "likely to be causal" relationship with metabolic
effects and a "suggestive of, but not sufficient to infer, a causal relationship" for central nervous
system effects, cardiovascular effects, and total mortality. The ISA reported that long-term
exposures (one month or longer) to ozone are "likely to be causal" for respiratory effects
including respiratory mortality, and a "suggestive of, but not sufficient to infer, a causal
relationship" for cardiovascular effects, reproductive effects, central nervous system effects,
metabolic effects, and total mortality.

The EPA estimates the incidence of air pollution effects for those health endpoints listed
above where the ISA classified the impact as either causal or likely-to-be-causal. Table 4-1
reports the effects we quantified and those we did not quantify in this RIA. The list of benefit
categories not quantified shown in that table is not exhaustive. And, among the effects we
quantified, we might not have been able to completely quantify either all human health impacts
or economic values. The table below omits any welfare effects such as biomass loss and foliar
injury. These effects are described in Chapter 7 of the Ozone NAAQS RIA (2015).

4-3


-------
Table 4-1: Human Health Effects of Ambient Ozone

Category

Effect

Effect
Quantified

Effect
Monetized

More
Information

Mortality from

Premature respiratory mortality from
short-term exposure (0-99)

V

V

Ozone ISA1

exposure to ozone

Premature respiratory mortality from
long-term exposure (age 30-99)

V

V

Ozone ISA



Hospital admissions—respiratory (ages
65-99)

V

V

Ozone ISA



Emergency department visits—
respiratory (ages 0-99)

V

V

Ozone ISA



Asthma onset (0-17)

V

V

Ozone ISA



Asthma symptoms/exacerbation
(asthmatics age 5-17)

V

V

Ozone ISA

Nonfatal morbidity
from exposure to

Allergic rhinitis (hay fever) symptoms
(ages 3-17)

V

V

Ozone ISA

Minor restricted-activity days (age 18-
65)

V

V

Ozone ISA

ozone

School absence days (age 5-17)

V

V

Ozone ISA



Decreased outdoor worker productivity
(age 18-65)

—

—

Ozone ISA2



Metabolic effects (e.g., diabetes)

—

—

Ozone ISA2



Other respiratory effects (e.g., premature
aging of lungs)

—

—

Ozone ISA2



Cardiovascular and nervous system
effects

—

—

Ozone ISA2



Reproductive and developmental effects

—

—

Ozone ISA2

1	We assess these benefits qualitatively due to data and resource limitations for this analysis. In other analyses we

quantified these effects as a sensitivity analysis.

2	We assess these benefits qualitatively because we do not have sufficient confidence in available data or methods.

4.2.1.2 Quantifying Cases of Ozone-A ttributable Premature Mortality

Mortality risk reductions account for the majority of monetized ozone-related benefits.
For this reason, this subsection and the following provide a brief background of the scientific
assessments that underly the quantification of these mortality risks and identifies the risk studies
used to quantify them in this RIA for ozone. As noted above, the Estimating PM2.5- and Ozone-
Attributable Health Benefits TSD describes fully the Agency's approach for quantifying the
number and value of ozone air pollution-related impacts, including additional discussion of how
the Agency selected the risk studies used to quantify them in this RIA. The TSD also includes
additional discussion of the assessments that support quantification of these mortality risk than
provide here.

In 2008, the National Academies of Science (NRC 2008) issued a series of
recommendations to EPA regarding the procedure for quantifying and valuing ozone-related

4-4


-------
mortality due to short-term exposures. Chief among these was that"... short-term exposure to
ambient ozone is likely to contribute to premature deaths" and the committee recommended that
"ozone-related mortality be included in future estimates of the health benefits of reducing ozone
exposures..." The NAS also recommended that".. .the greatest emphasis be placed on the
multicity and [National Mortality and Morbidity Air Pollution Studies (NMMAPS)] ... studies
without exclusion of the meta-analyses" (NRC 2008). Prior to the 2015 Ozone NAAQS RIA, the
Agency estimated ozone-attributable premature deaths using an NMMAPS-based analysis of
total mortality (Bell et al. 2004), two multi-city studies of cardiopulmonary and total mortality
(Huang et al. 2004; Schwartz 2005) and effect estimates from three meta-analyses of non-
accidental mortality (Bell et al. 2005; Ito et al. 2005; Levy et al. 2005). Beginning with the 2015
Ozone NAAQS RIA, the Agency began quantifying ozone-attributable premature deaths using
two newer multi-city studies of non-accidental mortality (Smith et al. 2009; Zanobetti and
Schwartz 2008) and one long-term cohort study of respiratory mortality (Jerrett et al. 2009). The
2020 Ozone ISA included changes to the causality relationship determinations between short-
term exposures and total mortality, as well as including more recent epidemiologic analyses of
long-term exposure effects on respiratory mortality (U.S. EPA, 2020). In this RIA, as described
in the corresponding TSD, two estimates of ozone-attributable respiratory deaths from short-term
exposures are estimated using the risk estimate parameters from Zanobetti et al. (2008) and
Katsouyanni et al. (2009). Ozone-attributable respiratory deaths from long-term exposures are
estimated using Turner et al. (2016). Due to time and resource limitations, we were unable to
reflect the warm season defined by Zanobetti et al. (2008) as June-August. Instead, we apply this
risk estimate to our standard warm season of May-September.

4.2.1.3 Economic Valuation

After quantifying the change in adverse health impacts, we estimate the economic value
of these avoided impacts. Reductions in ambient concentrations of air pollution generally lower
the risk of future adverse health effects by a small amount for a large population. Therefore, the
appropriate economic measure is willingness to pay (WTP) for changes in risk of a health effect.
For some health effects, such as hospital admissions, WTP estimates are generally not available,
so we use the cost of treating or mitigating the effect. These cost-of-illness (COI) estimates
generally (although not necessarily in every case) understate the true value of reductions in risk

4-5


-------
of a health effect. They tend to reflect the direct expenditures related to treatment but not the
value of avoided pain and suffering from the health effect. The unit values applied in this
analysis are provided in Section 5.1 of the TSD for the Revised Cross State Update rule (U.S.
EPA, 2021).

Avoided premature deaths account for 95 percent of monetized Ozone-related benefits.
The economics literature concerning the appropriate method for valuing reductions in premature
mortality risk is still developing. The value for the projected reduction in the risk of premature
mortality is the subject of continuing discussion within the economics and public policy analysis
community. Following the advice of the SAB's Environmental Economics Advisory Committee
(SAB-EEAC), the EPA currently uses the value of statistical life (VSL) approach in calculating
estimates of mortality benefits, because we believe this calculation provides the most reasonable
single estimate of an individual's WTP for reductions in mortality risk (U.S. EPA-SAB, 2000).
The VSL approach is a summary measure for the value of small changes in mortality risk
experienced by a large number of people.

The EPA continues work to update its guidance on valuing mortality risk reductions and
consulted several times with the SAB-EEAC on the issue. Until updated guidance is available,
the EPA determined that a single, peer-reviewed estimate applied consistently best reflects the
SAB-EEAC advice it has received. Therefore, the EPA applies the VSL that was vetted and
endorsed by the SAB in the Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses while the EPA
continues its efforts to update its guidance on this issue (U.S. EPA, 2016). This approach
calculates a mean value across VSL estimates derived from 26 labor market and contingent
valuation studies published between 1974 and 1991. The mean VSL across these studies is $10.7
million ($2016).31

The EPA is committed to using scientifically sound, appropriately reviewed evidence in
valuing changes in the risk of premature death and continues to engage with the SAB to identify
scientifically sound approaches to update its mortality risk valuation estimates. Most recently,
the Agency proposed new meta-analytic approaches for updating its estimates which were
subsequently reviewed by the SAB-EEAC. The EPA is taking the SAB's formal
recommendations under advisement (U.S. EPA, 2017b).

31 In 1990$, this base VSL is $4.8 million. In 2016$, this base VSL is $10.7 million.

4-6


-------
Because short-term ozone-related premature mortality occurs within the analysis year, the
estimated ozone-related benefits are identical for all discount rates. When valuing changes in
ozone-attributable deaths using the Turner et al. (2016) study, we follow advice provided by the
Health Effects Subcommittee of the SAB, which found that. .there is no evidence in the
literature to support a different cessation lag between ozone and particulate matter. The HES
therefore recommends using the same cessation lag structure and assumptions as for particulate
matter when utilizing cohort mortality evidence for ozone" (U.S. EPA-SAB 2010).

These estimated health benefits do not account for the influence of future changes in the
climate on ambient concentrations of pollutants (USGCRP 2016). For example, recent research
suggests that future changes to climate may create conditions more conducive to forming ozone.
The estimated health benefits also do not consider the potential for climate-induced changes in
temperature to modify the relationship between ozone and the risk of premature mortality (Jhun
et al. 2014; Ren et al. 2008a, 2008b).

4.2.1.4 Benefit-per-Ton Estimates

Because the estimated emissions reductions due to this rule are small and because we
cannot be confident of the location of new facilities under the NSPS, EPA elected to use the
benefit per-ton (BPT) approach. BPT estimates provide the total monetized human health
benefits (the sum of premature mortality and premature morbidity) of reducing one ton of the
VOC precursor for ozone from a specified source. Specifically, in this analysis, we multiplied
the estimates from the "Gasoline Distribution" sector by the corresponding emission reductions.
The method used to derive these estimates is described in the BPT Technical Support Document
(BPT TSD) on Estimating the Benefit per Ton of Reducing Directly-Emitted PM2.5,PM2.5
Precursors and Ozone Precursors from 21 Sectors and its precursors from 21 sectors (U.S. EPA,
2021). One limitation of using the BPT approach is an inability to provide estimates of the health
benefits associated with exposure to HAP, CO, and NO2.

As noted below in the characterization of uncertainty, all BPT estimates have inherent
limitations. Specifically, all national-average BPT estimates reflect the geographic distribution of
the modeled emissions, which may not exactly match the emission reductions that would occur
due to the action, and they may not reflect local variability in population density, meteorology,
exposure, baseline health incidence rates, or other local factors for any specific location. Given

4-7


-------
sector specific air quality modeling and the small changes in emissions considered in this action,
the difference in the quantified health benefits that result from the BPT approach compared with
if EPA had used a full-form air quality model should be minimal.

Over the last year and a half, the EPA systematically compared the changes in benefits,
and concentrations where available, from its BPT technique and other reduced-form techniques
to the changes in benefits and concentrations derived from full-form photochemical model
representation of a few different specific emissions scenarios. Reduced form tools are less
complex than the full air quality modeling, requiring less agency resources and time. That work,
in which we also explore other reduced form models is referred to as the "Reduced Form Tool
Evaluation Project" (Project), began in 2017, and the initial results were available at the end of
2018. The Agency's goal was to create a methodology by which investigators could better
understand the suitability of alternative reduced-form air quality modeling techniques for
estimating the health impacts of criteria pollutant emissions changes in the EPA's benefit-cost
analysis, including the extent to which reduced form models may over- or under-estimate
benefits (compared to full-scale modeling) under different scenarios and air quality
concentrations. The EPA Science Advisory Board (SAB) recently convened a panel to review
this report.32 In particular, the SAB will assess the techniques the Agency used to appraise these
tools; the Agency's approach for depicting the results of reduced-form tools; and steps the
Agency might take for improving the reliability of reduced-form techniques for use in future
Regulatory Impact Analyses (RIAs).

The scenario-specific emission inputs developed for this project are currently available
online. The study design and methodology are described in the final report summarizing the
results of the project (IEc, 2019. Evaluating Reduced-Form Tools for Estimating Air Quality
Benefits. Final Report). Results of this project found that total PM2.5 BPT values were within
approximately 10 percent of the health benefits calculated from full-form air quality modeling
when analyzing the Pulp and Paper sector, a sector used as an example for evaluating the
application of the new methodology in the final report. The ratios for individual species varied,
and the report found that the ratio for the directly emitted PM2.5 for the pulp and paper sector was
0.7 for the BPT approach compared to 1.0 for full air quality modeling combined with BenMAP.

32 85 FR 23823. April 29, 2020.

4-8


-------
This provides some initial understanding of the uncertainty which is associated with using the
BPT approach instead of full air quality modeling.

4.2.2	Ozone Vegetation Effects

Exposure to ozone has been found to be associated with a wide array of vegetation and
ecosystem effects in the published literature (U.S. EPA, 2020). Sensitivity to ozone is highly
variable across species, with over 66 vegetation species identified as "ozone-sensitive," many of
which occur in state and national parks and forests. These effects include those that cause
damage to, or impairment of, the intended use of the plant or ecosystem. Such effects are
considered adverse to public welfare and can include reduced growth and/or biomass production
in sensitive trees, reduced yield and quality of crops, visible foliar injury, changed to species
composition, and changes in ecosystems and associated ecosystem services.

4.2.3	Ozone Climate Effects

Ozone is a well-known short-lived climate forcing GHG (U.S. EPA, 2013). Stratospheric
ozone (the upper ozone layer) is beneficial because it protects life on Earth from the sun's
harmful ultraviolet (UV) radiation. In contrast, tropospheric ozone (ozone in the lower
atmosphere) is a harmful air pollutant that adversely affects human health and the environment
and contributes significantly to regional and global climate change. Due to its short atmospheric
lifetime, tropospheric ozone concentrations exhibit large spatial and temporal variability (U.S.
EPA, 2009b). The IPCC AR5 estimated that the contribution to current warming levels of
increased tropospheric ozone concentrations resulting from human methane, NOx, and VOC
emissions was 0.5 W/m2, or about 30 percent as large a warming influence as elevated CO2
concentrations. This quantifiable influence of ground level ozone on climate leads to increases in
global surface temperature and changes in hydrological cycles.

4.3 VOC-Related Ozone Benefits Results

Table 4-2 lists the estimated ozone-related benefits per ton applied in this national level
analysis. Benefits are estimated for both short- and long-term exposure to ozone. These results
are denoted as (ST) and (LT), respectively, and discounted at 3 and 7 percent for a 2019 currency
year. Table 4-3 presents the estimated ozone benefits from emission reductions for the GACT
6B (area source) portion of this action. Table 4-4 presents the estimated ozone benefits from

4-9


-------
emission reductions for the MACT R (major source) portion of this action. Table 4-5 shows the
estimated ozone-related benefits per ton applied in this analysis for affected the NSPS XXa (new
units) portion of this action, respectively. Finally, Table 4-6 presents the total health related
benefits of reducing emissions of ozone for all three rules. For all estimates, we summarize the
monetized ozone-related health benefits using discount rates of 3 percent and 7 percent for both
short-term and long-term effects for the 15-year analysis period of these rules discounted back to
2022 rounded to 2 significant figures. The PV of the benefits for the recommended options for
these rules is $220 million at the 3 percent discount rate to $130 million at the 7 percent discount
rate for the short-term benefits with an EAV of $18 to $14 million, respectively. The PV of the
benefits for the recommended options for these rules are $1,800 million at the 3 percent discount
rate to $1,000 million at the 7 percent discount rate for the long-term benefits with an EAV of
$150 million to $117 million, respectively. For the full set of underlying calculations see the
Gasoline Distribution Benefits workbook (docket number EPA-HQ-OAR-2020-0371).

Table 4-2: Gasoline Distribution: Short-term and Long-term Benefit per Ton Estimates of
Ozone-Attributable Premature Mortality and Illness for the Proposal, 2025-2040 ($2019)

Discount Rate

Year



(ST) 3 Percent (LT)



(ST) 7 Percent (LT)

2025

$881

and

$6,797

$785

and

$6,085

2030

$946

and

$7,561

$845

and

$6,765

2035

$1,006

and

$8,400

$903

and

$7,519

2040

$1,059

and

$9,144

$953

and

$8,188

Note: The standard reporting convention for EPA benefits is to round all results to two significant figures. Here, we report all
significant figures so that readers may reproduce the results reported below.

4-10


-------
Table 4-3: Gasoline Distribution GACT 6B: Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits Estimates of Ozone-Attributable
Premature Mortality and Illness (million 2019$)a'b'c	

GACT 6B

Less Stringent Regulatory Option	Proposed Regulatory Option	More Stringent Regulatory Option

Discount Rate	Discount Rate	Discount Rate

(ST) 3 Percent	(ST) 7 Percent

(LT)	(LT)	(ST) 3 Percent (LT)	(ST) 7 Percent (LT)	(ST) 3 Percent (LT)	(ST) 7 Percent (LT)

PV 52 and 427 32 and 256	184 and 1500	lTI and 900	228 and 1900	137 and 1100

EAV 4.4 and 36 3.5 and 28	15 and 126	12 and 99	19 and 160	15 and 120

"Discounted to 2022. Calculations of PV and EAV reflect benefits estimates for the 2026-2040 analysis timeframe described in Chapter 1 of this RIA.
bRounded to 2 significant figures.

°Benefits are estimated for both short- (ST) and long-term (LT) exposure to ozone.

Table 4-4: Gasoline Distribution MACT R: Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits Estimates of Ozone-Attributable
Premature Mortality and Illness (million 2019$)a'b'c	

MACT R

Less Stringent Regulatory Option	Proposed Regulatory Option	More Stringent Regulatory Option

Discount Rate	Discount Rate	Discount Rate

(ST) 3 Percent	(ST) 7 Percent

(LT)	(LT)	(ST) 3 Percent (LT)	(ST) 7 Percent (LT)	(ST) 3 Percent (LT)	(ST) 7 Percent (LT)

PV 21 and 17 L3 and 10	93 and 81	5~6 and 48	12 and 98	12 and 59

EAV 0.18 and 1.4 0.14 and 1.1	0.83 and 6.8	0.65 and 5.3	1.0 and 8.2	0.80 and 6.5

"Discounted to 2022. Calculations of PV and EAV reflect benefits estimates for the 2026-2040 analysis timeframe described in Chapter 1 of this RIA.
bRounded to 2 significant figures.

°Benefits are estimated for both short- (ST) and long-term (LT) exposure to ozone.

4-11


-------
Table 4-5: Gasoline Distribution NSPS XXa: Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits Estimates of Ozone-Attributable
Premature Mortality and Illness (million 2019$)a'b'c	

NSPS XX

Less Stringent Regulatory Option	Proposed Regulatory Option	More Stringent Regulatory Option

Discount Rate	Discount Rate	Discount Rate

(ST) 3 Percent	(ST) 7 Percent

(LT)	(LT)	(ST) 3 Percent (LT)	(ST) 7 Percent (LT)	(ST) 3 Percent (LT)	(ST) 7 Percent (LT)

PV 2A and 20	13 and II	29 and 240	16 and 130	29 and 240	16 and 130

EAV 0.20 and 1.6 0.15 and 1.2	2.4 and 20	1.8 and 15	2.4 and 20	1.8 and 15

"Discounted to 2022. Calculations of PV and EAV reflect benefits estimates for the 2026-2040 analysis timeframe described in Chapter 1 of this RIA.
bRounded to 2 significant figures.

°Benefits are estimated for both short- (ST) and long-term (LT) exposure to ozone.

Table 4-6: Gasoline Distribution All Rules: Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits Estimates of Ozone-Attributable
Premature Mortality and Illness (million 2019$)a'b'c	

All Rules

Less Stringent Regulatory Option	Proposed Regulatory Option	More Stringent Regulatory Option

Discount Rate	Discount Rate	Discount Rate

(ST) 3 Percent	(ST) 7 Percent

(LT)	(LT)	(ST) 3 Percent (LT) (ST) 7 Percent (LT) (ST) 3 Percent (LT)	(ST) 7 Percent (LT)

PV 57 and 460 34 and 280 220 and 1,800 130 and 1,100	270 and 2,200 160 and 1,300

EAV 4.7 and 39 3.7 and 31	19 and 150	15 and 120	23 and 180	18 and 140

"Discounted to 2022. Calculations of PV and EAV reflect benefits estimates for the 2026-2040 analysis timeframe described in Chapter 1 of this RIA.
bRounded to 2 significant figures.

°Benefits are estimated for both short- (ST) and long-term (LT) exposure to ozone.

4-12


-------
4.4	Characterization of Uncertainty in the Monetized VOC Benefits

In any complex analysis using estimated parameters and inputs from a variety of models,
there are likely to be many sources of uncertainty. This analysis is no exception. This analysis
includes many data sources as inputs, including emission inventories, air quality data from
models (with their associated parameters and inputs), population data, population estimates,
health effect estimates from epidemiology studies, economic data for monetizing benefits, and
assumptions regarding the future state of the world (i.e., regulations, technology, and human
behavior). Each of these inputs are uncertain and generate uncertainty in the benefits estimate.
When the uncertainties from each stage of the analysis are compounded, even small uncertainties
can have large effects on the total quantified benefits. Therefore, the estimates of annual benefits
should be viewed as representative of the magnitude of benefits expected, rather than the actual
benefits that would occur every year.

This RIA does not include the type of detailed uncertainty assessment found in the 2021
Revised Cross State Update RIA because we lack the necessary air quality input and monitoring
data. Criteria pollutant emissions changes were relatively small on a percentage basis, which
made air quality modeling impractical. However, the results of the uncertainty analyses
presented in the 2021 Revised Cross State Update RIA can provide some information regarding
the uncertainty inherent in the benefits results presented in this analysis.

4.5	Health Effects from Exposure to Hazardous Air Pollutants (HAP)

In the subsequent sections, we describe the health effects associated with the main HAP
of concern from the gasoline distribution sector: benzene (Section 4.5.1), hexane (Section 4.5.2),
toluene (Section 4.5.3), 2,2,4-Trimethylpentane (Section 4.5.4), naphthalene (Section 4.5.5),
ethylbenzene (Section 4.5.6), and xylenes (Section 4.5.7). This proposal is projected to reduce
37,000 tons of HAP emissions over the 2026 through 2040 period, with 31,000 tons of the
projected reductions coming from the proposed amendments to GACT 6B. With the data
available, it was not possible to estimate the change in emissions of each individual HAP.

Monetization of the benefits of reductions in cancer incidences requires several important
inputs, including central estimates of cancer risks, estimates of exposure to carcinogenic HAP,

4-13


-------
and estimates of the value of an avoided case of cancer (fatal and non-fatal). Due to methodology
and data limitations, we did not attempt to monetize the health benefits of reductions in HAP in
this analysis. Instead, we are providing a qualitative discussion of the health effects associated
with HAP emitted from sources subject to control under the proposed action. The EPA remains
committed to improving methods for estimating HAP benefits by continuing to explore
additional aspects of HAP-related risk from the gasoline distribution sector, including the
distribution of that risk.

4.5.1	Benzene

Benzene is used as a constituent in motor fuels and is found in gasoline service station
and motor vehicle exhaust emissions into air. Acute effects of benzene inhalation exposure in
humans include neurological symptoms such as drowsiness, dizziness, headaches, and
unconsciousness. Exposure to benzene vapor can cause eye, skin, and upper respiratory tract
irritation. Chronic exposure to benzene is associated with blood disorders, such as preleukemia
and aplastic anemia (ATSDR, 2007). The EPA's IRIS database lists benzene as a known human
carcinogen (causing leukemia) by all routes of exposure. IRIS found a causal relationship
between benzene exposure and acute lymphocytic leukemia and a suggestive relationship
between benzene exposure and chronic non-lymphocytic leukemia and chronic lymphocytic
leukemia (U.S. EPA, 2000). IARC has also determined that benzene is a human carcinogen
(IARC, 2018).

4.5.2	Hexane

Hexane is used to extract edible oils from seeds and vegetables, as a special-use solvent,
and as a cleaning agent (ATSDR, 1997). Acute (short-term) inhalation exposure of humans to
high levels of hexane causes mild central nervous system (CNS) effects, including dizziness,
giddiness, slight nausea, and headache. Exposure to hexane vapors can cause dermatitis and
irritation of the eyes and throat. Chronic (long-term) exposure to hexane in air is associated with
polyneuropathy in humans, with numbness in the extremities, muscular weakness, blurred vision,
headache, and fatigue observed (Sittig, 1985). In animal studies, neurotoxic effects as well as
pulmonary and nasal lesions have been observed (ATSDR, 1997). EPA determined that hexane
was not classifiable as to human carcinogenicity (U.S. EPA, 2005).

4-14


-------
4.5.3	Toluene

Toluene is added to gasoline, used to produce benzene, and used as a
solvent. Automobile emissions are the principal source of toluene to the ambient air. Toluene
exposure causes toxicity to the central nervous system (CNS) in both humans and animals for
acute (short-term) and chronic (long-term) exposures (ATSDR, 2000). CNS dysfunction and
narcosis have been frequently observed in humans acutely exposed to elevated airborne levels of
toluene; symptoms include fatigue, sleepiness, headaches, and nausea. CNS depression has been
reported to occur in chronic abusers exposed to high levels of toluene. Chronic inhalation
exposure of humans to toluene also causes irritation of the upper respiratory tract and eyes, sore
throat, dizziness, and headache. Human studies have reported developmental effects, such as
CNS dysfunction, attention deficits, and minor craniofacial and limb anomalies, in the children
of pregnant women exposed to high levels of toluene or mixed solvents by inhalation (ATSDR,
2000). EPA has concluded that that there is inadequate information to assess the carcinogenic
potential of toluene (U.S. EPA, 2005).

4.5.4	2,2,4-Trimethylpentane

2,2,4-Trimethylpentane is released to the environment through the manufacture, use, and
disposal of products associated with the petroleum and gasoline industry. In an isolated acute
exposure incident, 2,2,4-trimethylpentane penetrated the skin of a human which led to skin
necrosis and required surgery. In animals acutely exposed via inhalation or injection irritation of
the lungs, edema, CNS depression, and hemorrhage have been observed. In rats chronically
exposed kidney and liver effects have been observed in rats exposed orally or by inhalation
(HSDB, 1993). EPA has not classified 2,2,4-trimethylpentane with respect to potential
carcinogenicity (U.S. EPA, 2007).

4.5.5	Napthalene

Naphthalene is used in the production of phthalic anhydride; it is also used in
mothballs. Acute exposure of humans to naphthalene by inhalation, ingestion, and dermal
contact is associated with hemolytic anemia and neurological damage. Cataracts have also been
reported in workers acutely exposed to naphthalene by inhalation and ingestion. Chronic (long-
term) exposure of workers and rodents to naphthalene has been reported to cause cataracts and

4-15


-------
damage to the retina. Hemolytic anemia has been reported in infants born to mothers who
"sniffed" and ingested naphthalene (as mothballs) during pregnancy. Inflammation, hyperplasia,
and lesions have been reported in the nose of rats exposed chronically to naphthalene (ATSDR
2005; EPA, 1998). Based on the 1996 Proposed Guidelines for Carcinogen Risk Assessment,
EPA determined there was insufficient information to assess the carcinogenic potential of
naphthalene (EPA, 1998). IARC classified naphthalene as possibly carcinogenic to humans,
Group 2B (IARC, 2002).

4.5.6	Ethylbenzene

Acute (short-term) exposure to ethylbenzene in humans results in respiratory effects, such
as throat irritation and chest constriction, irritation of the eyes, and neurological effects such as
dizziness. Chronic (long-term) exposure to ethylbenzene by inhalation in humans has shown
conflicting results regarding its effects on the blood. Animal studies have reported effects on the
blood, liver, and kidneys from chronic inhalation exposure to ethylbenzene (ATSDR,
2010). Limited information is available on the carcinogenic effects of ethylbenzene in humans.
In a study by the National Toxicology Program (NTP), exposure to ethylbenzene by inhalation
resulted in an increased incidence of kidney and testicular tumors in rats, and lung and liver
tumors in mice (NTP, 1999). EPA has classified ethylbenzene as a Group D, not classifiable as
to human carcinogenicity (EPA, 1988). IARC classified ethylbenzene as a Group 2B carcinogen,
possibly carcinogenic to humans (IARC, 2000).

4.5.7	Xylenes

Xylenes are released into the atmosphere as fugitive emissions from industrial sources,
from auto exhaust, and through volatilization from their use as solvents. Acute (short-term)
inhalation exposure to mixed xylenes in humans results in irritation of the eyes, nose, and throat,
gastrointestinal effects, eye irritation, and neurological effects. Chronic (long-term) inhalation
exposure of humans to mixed xylenes results primarily in CNS effects, such as headache,
dizziness, fatigue, tremors, and incoordination; respiratory, cardiovascular, and kidney effects
have also been reported (ATSDR, 2007; EPA, 2003). EPA determined that mixed xylenes are
not classifiable as to human carcinogenicity (EPA, 2003).

4-16


-------
4.5.8	Cumene

Cumene is used in petroleum products. Acute (short-term) inhalation exposure to
cumene may cause headaches, dizziness, drowsiness, slight incoordination, and unconsciousness
in humans. Cumene is a potent central nervous system (CNS) depressant and a skin and eye
irritant (U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, 1993). No information is available on
the chronic (long-term) effects of cumene in humans. Animal studies have reported increased
liver, kidney, and adrenal weights from inhalation exposure to cumene. EPA has classified
cumene as a Group D, not classifiable as to human carcinogenicity (U.S. EPA, 1997). IARC has
classified cumene as possibly carcinogenic to humans (Group 2B) based on sufficient evidence
of carcinogenicity in animals. Exposure to cumene by whole-body inhalation caused increased
incidence of tumors in the respiratory tract, kidney, spleen, and liver in animal studies (IARC,
2013).

4.5.9	Other Air Toxics

In addition to the compounds described above, other toxic compounds might be affected
by this action. Information regarding the health effects of those compounds can be found in the
EPA's IRIS database33.

4.6 Climate Impacts

With the additional operation of control devices associated with the proposed action, CO2
emissions will be generated as a result of the additional electricity required to operate them. The
estimate of additional CO2 emissions is presented in Chapter 3. There will be climate disbenefits
associated with these additional CO2 emissions that we calculate using an interim measure of the
social cost of carbon (SC-CO2).

Elevated concentrations of CO2 and other greenhouse gases (GHGs) in the atmosphere
have been warming the planet, leading to changes in the Earth's climate including changes in the
frequency and intensity of heat waves, precipitation, and extreme weather events, rising seas, and
retreating snow and ice. The well-documented atmospheric changes due to anthropogenic GHG

33 U.S. EPA Integrated Risk Information System (IRIS) database is available at www.epa.gov/iris. Accessed March
30, 2022.

4-17


-------
emissions are changing the climate at a pace and in a way that threatens human health, society,
and the natural environment.

Extensive information on climate change is available in the scientific assessments and
EPA documents that are briefly described in this section, as well as in the technical and scientific
information supporting them. One of those documents is EPA's 2009 Endangerment and Cause
or Contribute Findings for Greenhouse Gases Under section 202(a) of the CAA (74 FR 66496,
December 15, 2009). In the 2009 Endangerment Finding, the Administrator found under section
202(a) of the CAA that elevated atmospheric concentrations of six key well-mixed GHGs - CO2,
methane (CH4), nitrous oxide (N2O), HFCs, perfluorocarbons (PFCs), and sulfur hexafluoride
(SF6) - "may reasonably be anticipated to endanger the public health and welfare of current and
future generations" (74 FR 66523). The 2009 Endangerment Finding, together with the extensive
scientific and technical evidence in the supporting record, documented that climate change
caused by human emissions of GHGs threatens the public health of the U.S. population. It
explained that by raising average temperatures, climate change increases the likelihood of heat
waves, which are associated with increased deaths and illnesses (74 FR 66497). While climate
change also increases the likelihood of reductions in cold-related mortality, evidence indicates
that the increases in heat mortality will be larger than the decreases in cold mortality in the U.S.
(74 FR 66525). The 2009 Endangerment Finding further explained that compared with a future
without climate change, climate change is expected to increase tropospheric ozone pollution over
broad areas of the U.S., including in the largest metropolitan areas with the worst tropospheric
ozone problems, and thereby increase the risk of adverse effects on public health (74 FR 66525).
Climate change is also expected to cause more intense hurricanes and more frequent and intense
storms of other types and heavy precipitation, with impacts on other areas of public health, such
as the potential for increased deaths, injuries, infectious and waterborne diseases, and stress-
related disorders (74 FR 66525). Children, the elderly, and the poor are among the most
vulnerable to these climate-related health effects (74 FR 66498).

The 2009 Endangerment Finding also documented, together with the extensive scientific
and technical evidence in the supporting record, that climate change touches nearly every aspect
of public welfare in the U.S. with resulting economic costs, including: changes in water supply
and quality due to changes in drought and extreme rainfall events; increased risk of storm surge
and flooding in coastal areas and land loss due to inundation; increases in peak electricity

4-18


-------
demand and risks to electricity infrastructure; and the potential for significant agricultural
disruptions and crop failures (though offset to some extent by carbon fertilization). These
impacts are also global and the effects of climate change occurring outside the U.S. are
reasonably expected to impact the U.S. population. (74 FR 66530).

In 2016, the Administrator issued a similar finding for GHG emissions from aircraft
under section 231(a)(2)(A) of the CAA. In the 2016 Endangerment Finding, the Administrator
found that the body of scientific evidence amassed in the record for the 2009 Endangerment
Finding compellingly supported a similar endangerment finding under CAA section
231(a)(2)(A), and also found that the science assessments released between the 2009 and the
2016 Findings "strengthen and further support the judgment that GHGs in the atmosphere may
reasonably be anticipated to endanger the public health and welfare of current and future
generations" (81 FR 54424).

Since the 2016 Endangerment Finding, the climate change impacts have continued to
intensify, with new observational records being set for several climate indicators such as global
average surface temperatures, GHG concentrations, and sea level rise. Moreover, heavy
precipitation events have increased in the eastern United States while agricultural and ecological
drought has increased in the western United States along with more intense and larger wildfires.34
Recent assessment reports discuss how these observed trends are increasingly attributed to
human-induced climate change35 and are expected to continue and worsen over the coming
century, with stronger trends under higher warming scenarios (see e.g., USGCRP (2018), IPCC
(2022a, 2022b)). Climate impacts that occur outside U.S. borders also increasingly impact the
welfare of individuals and firms that reside in the United States because of their connection to
the global economy. This will occur through the effect of climate change on international
markets, trade, tourism, and other activities. For example, supply chain disruptions are a
prominent pathway through which U.S. business and consumers are, and will continue to be,

34	See EPA's November 2021 Proposed Standards of Performance for New, Reconstructed, and Modified Sources

and Emissions Guidelines for Existing Sources: Oil and Natural Gas Sector Climate Review
(https://www.govinfo.gov/content/pkg/FR-2021-l l-15/pdf/202l-24202.pdf) for more discussion of specific
examples. An additional resource for indicators can be found at https://www.epa.gov/climate-indicators.

35	For example, "[fjield evidence shows that anthropogenic climate change has increased the area burned by wildfire

above natural levels in western North America from 1984-2017 by double forthe Western US A... {high
confidence)" (IPCC (2022a), p. 2-5).

4-19


-------
affected by climate change impacts abroad (USGCRP 2018, U.S. DOD 2021). Additional
climate change induced international spillovers can occur through pathways such as damages
across transboundary resources, economic and political destabilization, and global migration that
can lead to adverse impacts on U.S. national security, public health, and humanitarian concerns
(U.S. DOD 2014, CCS 2018). These and other trends highlight the increased risk already being
experienced due to climate change as detailed in the 2009 and 2016 Endangerment Findings.
Additionally, new major scientific assessments continue to advance our understanding of the
climate system and the impacts that GHGs have on public health and welfare both for current
and future generations. These assessments include:

•	U.S. Global Change Research Program's (USGCRP) 2016 Climate and Health Assessment and 2017-2018
Fourth National Climate Assessment (NCA4) (USGCRP 2016, 2017, 2018).

•	IPCC's 2018 Global Warming of 1.5 °C, 2019 Climate Change and Land, and the 2019 Ocean and
Cryosphere in a Changing Climate assessments, as well as the 2021 IPCC Sixth Assessment Report (AR6)
(IPCC 2018, 2019a, 2019b, 2021).

•	The National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and Medicine's 2016 Attribution of Extreme Weather
Events in the Context of Climate Change, 2017 Valuing Climate Damages: Updating Estimation of the
Social Cost of Carbon Dioxide, and 2019 Climate Change and Ecosystems assessments (NAS 2016, 2017,
2019).

•	National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration's (NOAA) annual State of the Climate reports
published by the Bulletin of the American Meteorological Society, most recently in August of 2020
(Blunden and Arndt 2020).

•	EPA Climate Change and Social Vulnerability in the United States: A Focus on Six Impacts (2021) (EPA
2021a).

Net climate benefits (disbenefits) from reducing (increasing) emissions of CO2 can be
monetized using estimates of the social cost of carbon (SC-CO2). However, as explained below,
due to a court order, EPA cannot present these monetized estimates in the analysis of this action
at this time. The SC-CO2 is the monetary value of the net harm to society associated with a
marginal increase in CO2 emissions in a given year, or the benefit of avoiding that increase. In
principle, SC-CO2 includes the value of all climate change impacts (both negative and positive),
including (but not limited to) changes in net agricultural productivity, human health effects,
property damage from increased flood risk, natural disasters, disruption of energy systems, risk
of conflict, environmental migration, and the value of ecosystem services. The SC-CO2,
therefore, should reflect the societal value of reducing (or increasing) emissions of the gas in
question by one metric ton. The SC-CO2 is, therefore, an estimate of the marginal benefit of CO2
abatement along the baseline and the theoretically appropriate value to use in conducting benefit-
cost analyses of policies that affect CO2 emissions. In practice, data and modeling limitations

4-20


-------
naturally restrain the ability of SC-CO2 estimates to include all of the important physical,
ecological, and economic impacts of climate change, such that the estimates are a partial
accounting of climate change impacts and will therefore, tend to be underestimates of the
marginal benefits of abatement.

EPA and other federal agencies began regularly incorporating SC-CO2 estimates in
benefit-cost analyses conducted under Executive Order (E.O.) 1286636 in 2008, following a court
ruling in which an agency was ordered to consider the value of reducing CO2 emissions in a
rulemaking process. Specifically, the U.S. Ninth Circuit Court of Appeals remanded a fuel
economy rule to DOT for failing to monetize CO2 emission reductions, stating that "while the
record shows that there is a range of values, the value of carbon emissions reduction is certainly
not zero."37 In 2009, the U.S. Government (USG) launched an interagency process, under the
leadership of the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) and the Council of Economic
Advisers (CEA), to ensure that Federal agencies had access to the best available information
when quantifying the benefits of reducing CO2 emissions in regulatory impact analyses and to
promote consistency in the estimated values. This included the establishment of an interagency
working group (IWG) which represented perspectives and technical expertise from many federal
agencies and a commitment to following the peer-reviewed literature. In 2010, the IWG finalized
a set of four SC-CO2 values recommended for use in regulatory analyses and presented them in a
technical support document (TSD) that also provided guidance for agencies on how to use the
estimates (IWG 2010). The SC-CO2 estimates recommended in 2010 were developed from an
ensemble of three widely cited integrated assessment models (IAMs) that estimate global climate
damages using highly aggregated representations of climate processes and the global economy
combined into a single modeling framework. The three IAMs were run using a common set of
input assumptions in each model for future population, economic, and GHG emissions growth,
as well as equilibrium climate sensitivity (ECS) - a measure of the globally averaged
temperature response to increased atmospheric CO2 concentrations. These estimates were

36	Under E.O. 12866, agencies are required, to the extent permitted by law and where applicable, "to assess both the
costs and the benefits of the intended regulation and, recognizing that some costs and benefits are difficult to
quantify, propose or adopt a regulation only upon a reasoned determination that the benefits of the intended
regulation justify its costs." Some statutes also require agencies to conduct at least some of the same analyses

required under E.O. 12866, such as the Energy Policy and Conservation Act, which mandates the setting of fuel
economy regulations.

37	Ctr. for Biological Diversity v. Nat'l Highway Traffic Safety Admin., 538 F.3d 1172, 1200 (9th Cir. 2008).

4-21


-------
updated in 2013 based on new versions of each IAM. In August 2016 the IWG published
estimates of the social cost of methane (SC-CH4) and nitrous oxide (SC-N20) using
methodologies that are consistent with the methodology underlying the SC-CO2 estimates. In
January 2017, the National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and Medicine issued
recommendations for an updating process to ensure the estimates continue to reflect the best
available science (National Academies 2017). In March 2017, Executive Order 13783 disbanded
the IWG and instructed agencies when monetizing the value of changes in greenhouse gas
emissions resulting from regulations to follow the Office of Management and Budget's (OMB)
Circular A-4.

On January 20, 2021, President Biden issued E.O. 13990 which re-established the IWG
and asked it to update the estimates of SC-CO2, SC-CH4, and SC-N2O (collectively referred to as
social cost of greenhouse gases (SC-GHG)) used by the U.S. Government (USG) to reflect the
best available science and the recommendations of the National Academies (2017). On February
26, 2021, the IWG recommended as interim SC-GHG estimates the most recent estimates
developed by the IWG prior to the group being disbanded in 2017. The February 2021 TSD
stated that the interim estimates reflected the best available scientific estimates available for
agencies to use in regulatory benefit-cost analyses and other applications while the more
comprehensive review was underway.

The SC-CO2 is the monetary value of the net harm to society associated with a marginal
increase in CO2 emissions in a given year, or the benefit of avoiding that increase. In principle,
SC-CO2 includes the value of all climate change impacts, including (but not limited to) changes
in net agricultural productivity, human health effects, property damage from increased flood risk
and natural disasters, disruption of energy systems, risk of conflict, environmental migration, and
the value of ecosystem services. The SC-CO2, therefore, reflects the societal value of reducing
emissions of the gas in question by one metric ton. The SC-CO2 is the theoretically appropriate
values to use in conducting benefit-cost analyses of policies that affect CO2 emissions.

We estimate the global social disbenefits of CO2 emission increases expected from the
proposed action using the SC-CO2 estimates presented in the Technical Support Document:
Social Cost of Carbon, Methane, and Nitrous Oxide Interim Estimates under Executive Order
13990 (IWG 2021) (hereafter, "February 2021 TSD"). We have evaluated the SC-GHG

4-22


-------
estimates in the February 2021 TSD and have determined that these estimates are appropriate for
use in estimating the global social benefits of CO2 emission reductions expected from this
proposed action. These SC-CO2 estimates are interim values developed under Executive Order
(E.O.) 13990 for use in benefit-cost analyses until an improved estimate of the impacts of
climate change can be developed based on the best available science and economics. After
considering the TSD, and the issues and studies discussed therein, EPA finds that these
estimates, while likely an underestimate, are the best currently available SC-GHG estimates.

The SC-CO2 estimates presented here were developed over many years, using transparent
process, peer-reviewed methodologies, the best science available at the time of that process, and
with input from the public. Specifically, in 2009, an interagency working group (IWG) that
included the EPA and other executive branch agencies and offices was established to ensure that
agencies were using the best available. The IWG published SC-CO2 estimates in 2010 that were
developed from an ensemble of three widely cited integrated assessment models (IAMs) that
estimate global climate damages using highly aggregated representations of climate processes
and the global economy combined into a single modeling framework. The three IAMs were run
using a common set of input assumptions in each model for future population, economic, and
CO2 emissions growth, as well as equilibrium climate sensitivity (ECS) - a measure of the
globally averaged temperature response to increased atmospheric CO2 concentrations. These
estimates were updated in 2013 based on new versions of each IAM.38 In August 2016 the IWG
published estimates of the social cost of methane (SC-CH4) and nitrous oxide (SC-N2O) using
methodologies that are consistent with the methodology underlying the SC-CO2 estimates. In
2015, as part of the response to public comments received to a 2013 solicitation for comments on
the SC-CO2 estimates, the IWG announced a National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and
Medicine review of the SC-CO2 estimates to offer advice on how to approach future updates to
ensure that the estimates continue to reflect the best available science and methodologies. In
January 2017, the National Academies released their final report, Valuing Climate Damages:
Updating Estimation of the Social Cost of Carbon Dioxide, and recommended specific criteria
for future updates to the SC-CO2 estimates, a modeling framework to satisfy the specified

38 Dynamic Integrated Climate and Economy (DICE) 2010 (Nordhaus 2010), Climate Framework for Uncertainty,
Negotiation, and Distribution (FUND) 3.8 (Anthoff and Tol 2013a, 2013b), and Policy Analysis of the
Greenhouse Gas Effect (PAGE) 2009 (Hope 2013).

4-23


-------
criteria, and both near-term updates and longer-term research needs pertaining to various
components of the estimation process.39 Shortly thereafter, in March 2017, President Trump
issued Executive Order 13783, which disbanded the IWG, withdrew the previous TSDs, and
directed agencies to ensure SC-CO2 estimates used in regulatory analyses are consistent with the
guidance contained in OMB's Circular A-4, "including with respect to the consideration of
domestic versus international impacts and the consideration of appropriate discount rates" (E.O.
13783, Section 5(c)). Benefit-cost analyses following E.O. 13783, for example the benefit-cost
analysis in the proposal Industrial, Commercial and Institutional (ICI) Boilers RIA40 used SC-
CO2 estimates that attempted to focus on the domestic impacts of climate change as estimated by
the models to occur within U.S. borders and were calculated using two discount rates
recommended by Circular A-4, 3 percent and 7 percent. All other methodological decisions and
model versions used in SC- CO2 calculations remained the same as those used by the IWG in
2010 and 2013, respectively.

On January 20, 2021, President Biden issued Executive Order 13990, which re-
established the IWG and directed it to ensure that the U.S. Government's estimates of the social
cost of carbon, methane, and nitrous oxide (collectively referred to as SC-GHG) reflect the best
available science and the recommendations of the National Academies (2017). The IWG was
tasked with first reviewing the SC-GHG estimates currently used in Federal analyses and
publishing interim estimates within 30 days of the E.O. that reflect the full impact of GHG
emissions, including by taking global damages into account. As noted above, EPA participated in
the IWG but has also independently evaluated the interim SC-CO2 estimates published in the
February 2021 TSD and determined they are appropriate to use here to estimate the climate
benefits for this proposed action. EPA and other agencies intend to undertake a fuller update of
the SC-GHG estimates that takes into consideration the advice of the National Academies and
other recent scientific literature.

39	National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and Medicine (National Academies). 2017. Valuing Climate
Damages: Updating Estimation of the Social Cost of Carbon Dioxide. Washington, D.C.: National Academies
Press.

40	The values used in the proposal ICI Boilers RIA completed in 2020 were interim values developed under E.O.
13783 for use in regulatory analyses. EPA followed E.O. 13783 by using SC-C02 estimates reflecting impacts
occurring within U.S. borders and 3% and 7% discount rates in our central analysis for the proposal ICI Boilers
RIA.

4-24


-------
The EPA has also evaluated the content of the February 2021 TSD, including the studies and
methodological issues discussed therein and concludes that it agrees with the rationale for these
estimates presented in the TSD and summarized below.

In particular, the IWG found that the SC-GHG estimates used under E.O. 13783 fail to
reflect the full impact of GHG emissions in multiple ways. First, the IWG found that a global
perspective is essential for SC-GHG estimates because climate impacts occurring outside U.S.
borders can directly and indirectly affect the welfare of U.S. citizens and residents. Thus, U.S.
interests are affected by the climate impacts that occur outside U.S. borders. Examples of
affected interests include direct effects on U.S. citizens and assets located abroad, international
trade, U.S. military assets and interests abroad, and tourism, and spillover pathways such as
economic and political destabilization and global migration that can lead to adverse impacts on
U.S. national security, public health, and humanitarian concerns. In addition, assessing the
benefits of U.S. GHG mitigation activities requires consideration of how those actions may
affect mitigation activities by other countries, as those international mitigation actions will
provide a benefit to U.S. citizens and residents by mitigating climate impacts that affect U.S.
citizens and residents.

In addition, a wide range of scientific and economic experts have emphasized the issue of
reciprocity as support for considering global damages of GHG emissions. Using a global
estimate of damages in U.S. analyses of regulatory actions allows the U.S. to continue to actively
encourage other nations, including emerging major economies, to take significant steps to reduce
emissions. The only way to achieve an efficient allocation of resources for emissions reduction
on a global basis—and so benefit the U.S. and its citizens—is for all countries to base their
policies on global estimates of damages.

Therefore, in this proposed action EPA centers attention on a global measure of SC-
GHG. This approach is the same as that taken in EPA regulatory analyses over 2009 through
2016. Furthermore, as an empirical matter, the development of a domestic SC-GHG is greatly
complicated by the relatively few region- or country-specific estimates of the SC-CO2 in the
literature. At present, the only quantitative characterization of domestic damages from GHG
emissions is based on the share of damages arising from climate impacts occurring within U.S.
borders as represented in current IAMs. This is both incomplete and an underestimate of the

4-25


-------
share of total damages that accrue to the citizens and residents of the U.S. because these models
do not capture the regional interactions and spillovers discussed above. EPA, as a member of the
IWG, will continue to review developments in the literature, including more robust
methodologies for estimating SC-GHG values based on purely domestic damages, and explore
ways to better inform the public of the full range of carbon impacts, both global and domestic.

Second, the IWG found that the use of the social rate of return on capital (7 percent under
current OMB Circular A-4 guidance) to discount the future benefits of reducing GHG emissions
inappropriately underestimates the impacts of climate change for the purposes of estimating the
SC-GHG. Consistent with the findings of the National Academies and the economic literature,
the IWG continued to conclude that the consumption rate of interest is the theoretically
appropriate discount rate in an intergenerational context (IWG 2010, 2013, 2016a, 2016b), and
recommended that discount rate uncertainty and relevant aspects of intergenerational ethical
considerations be accounted for in selecting future discount rates.41 Furthermore, the damage
estimates developed for use in the SC-GHG are estimated in consumption-equivalent terms, and
so an application of OMB Circular A-4's guidance for regulatory analysis would then use the
consumption discount rate to calculate the SC-GHG. EPA agrees with this assessment and will
continue to follow developments in the literature pertaining to this issue. EPA also notes that
while OMB Circular A-4, as published in 2003, recommends using 3 percent and 7 percent
discount rates as "default" values, Circular A-4 also reminds agencies that "different regulations
may call for different emphases in the analysis, depending on the nature and complexity of the
regulatory issues and the sensitivity of the benefit and cost estimates to the key assumptions." On
discounting, Circular A-4 recognizes that "special ethical considerations arise when comparing
benefits and costs across generations," and Circular A-4 acknowledges that analyses may

41 Interagency Working Group on Social Cost of Carbon (IWG). 2010. Technical Support Document: Social Cost of
Carbon for Regulatory Impact Analysis under Executive Order 12866. February. United States Government.
Interagency Working Group on Social Cost of Carbon (IWG). 2013. Technical Support Document: Technical
Update of the Social Cost of Carbon for Regulatory Impact Analysis Under Executive Order 12866. May. United
States Government. Interagency Working Group on Social Cost of Greenhouse Gases (IWG). 2016a. Technical
Support Document: Technical Update of the Social Cost of Carbon for Regulatory Impact Analysis Under
Executive Order 12866. August. United States Government. Interagency Working Group on the Social Cost of
Greenhouse Gases. 2016b. Addendum to Technical Support Document on Social Cost of Carbon for Regulatory
Impact Analysis under Executive Order 12866: Application of the Methodology to Estimate the Social Cost of
Methane and the Social Cost of Nitrous Oxide. August. United Stated Government. Available at:

(accessed February 5, 2021).

4-26


-------
appropriately "discount future costs and consumption benefits.. .at a lower rate than for
intragenerational analysis." In the 2015 Response to Comments on the Social Cost of Carbon for
Regulatory Impact Analysis, OMB, EPA, and the other IWG members recognized that "Circular
A-4 is a living document" and "the use of 7 percent is not considered appropriate for
intergenerational discounting. There is wide support for this view in the academic literature, and
it is recognized in Circular A-4 itself." Thus, EPA concludes that a 7 percent discount rate is not
appropriate to apply to value the social cost of greenhouse gases in this regulatory analysis. In
this analysis, to calculate the present and annualized values of climate benefits, EPA uses the
same discount rate as the rate used to discount the value of damages from future GHG emissions,
for internal consistency. That approach to discounting follows the same approach that the
February 2021 TSD recommends "to ensure internal consistency—i.e., future damages from
climate change using the SC-GHG at 2.5 percent should be discounted to the base year of the
analysis using the same 2.5 percent rate." EPA has also consulted the National Academies' 2017
recommendations on how SC-GHG estimates can "be combined in RIAs with other cost and
benefits estimates that may use different discount rates." The National Academies reviewed
"several options," including "presenting all discount rate combinations of other costs and benefits
with [SC-GHG] estimates." Later in this RIA chapter, EPA presents all combinations of the SC-
GHG values at the different discount rates appropriate to climate effects (2.5 percent, 3 percent,
and 5 percent) together with other costs and benefits discounted at the 3 percent and 7 percent
rates, consistent with the options outlined by the National Academies.

While the IWG works to assess how best to incorporate the latest, peer reviewed science
to develop an updated set of SC-GHG estimates, it recommended the interim estimates to be the
most recent estimates developed by the IWG prior to the group being disbanded in 2017. The
estimates rely on the same models and harmonized inputs and are calculated using a range of
discount rates. As explained in the February 2021 TSD, the IWG has determined that it is
appropriate for agencies to revert to the same set of four values drawn from the SC-GHG
distributions based on three discount rates as were used in regulatory analyses between 2010 and
2016 and subject to public comment. For each discount rate, the IWG combined the
distributions across models and socioeconomic emissions scenarios (applying equal weight to
each) and then selected a set of four values for use in benefit-cost analyses: an average value
resulting from the model runs for each of three discount rates (2.5 percent, 3 percent, and 5

4-27


-------
percent), plus a fourth value, selected as the 95th percentile of estimates based on a 3 percent
discount rate. The fourth value was included to provide information on potentially higher-than-
expected economic impacts from climate change, conditional on the 3 percent estimate of the
discount rate. As explained in the February 2021 TSD, this update reflects the immediate need to
have an operational SC-GHG for use in regulatory benefit-cost analyses and other applications
that was developed using a transparent process, peer-reviewed methodologies, and the science
available at the time of that process. Those estimates were subject to public comment in the
context of dozens of proposed rulemakings as well as in a dedicated public comment period in
2013.

Table 4-7 summarizes the interim global SC-CO2 estimates for the years 2026 to 2040.
These estimates are reported in 2019$ but are otherwise identical to those presented in the IWG's
2016 TSD (IWG 2016a). For purposes of capturing uncertainty around the SC-CO2 estimates in
analyses, the IWG's February 2021 TSD emphasizes the importance of considering all four of
the SC-CO2 values. The SC-CO2 increases over time within the models - i.e., the societal harm
from one metric ton emitted in 2040 is higher than the harm caused by one metric ton emitted in
2026 - because future emissions produce larger incremental damages as physical and economic
systems become more stressed in response to greater climatic change, and because GDP is
growing over time and many damage categories are modeled as proportional to GDP.

Table 4-7: Interim Global Social Cost of Carbon Values, 2026-2040 (2019$/Metric Ton

	CO2)	

Discount Rate and Statistic

Year

5%

3%

2.50%

3%



Average

Average

Average

95th Percentile

2026

$17

$57

$83

$170

2027

$18

$58

$85

$170

2028

$18

$59

$86

$180

2029

$19

$60

$87

$180

2030

$19

$61

$88

$180

2031

$20

$62

$90

$190

2032

$20

$63

$91

$190

2033

$21

$64

$92

$200

2034

$21

$66

$94

$200

2035

$22

$67

$95

$200

2036

$23

$68

$96

$210

2037

$23

$69

$98

$210

2038

$24

$70

$99

$210

4-28


-------




Discount Rate and Statistic



Year

5%

3%

2.50%

3%



Average

Average

Average

95th Percentile

2039

$24

$71

$100

$220

2040

$25

$72

$100

$220

Note: These SC-CO2 values are identical to those reported in the 2016 TSD (IWG 2016a, cited in footnote 43 above)
adjusted for inflation to 2019$ using the annual GDP Implicit Price Deflator values in the U.S. Bureau of Economic
Analysis' (BEA) NIPA Table 1.1.9 found at https://fred.stlouisfed.org/release/tables?rid=53&eid=41158. The values
are stated in $/metric ton CO2 (1 metric ton equals 1.102 short tons) and vary depending on the year of CO2
emissions. This table displays the values rounded to the nearest dollar; the annual unrounded values used in the
calculations in this RIA are available on OMB's website: .

Source: https://www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/blog/2021/02/26/a-return-to-science-evidence-based-estimates-
of-the-benefits-of-reducing-climate-pollution/

There are a number of limitations and uncertainties associated with the SC-CO2 estimates
presented in Table 4-7. Some uncertainties are captured within the analysis, while other areas of
uncertainty have not yet been quantified in a way that can be modeled. Figure 4-1 presents the
quantified sources of uncertainty in the form of frequency distributions for the SC-CO2 estimates
for emissions in 2030. The distributions of SC-CO2 estimates reflect uncertainty in key model
parameters such as the equilibrium climate sensitivity, as well as uncertainty in other parameters
set by the original model developers. To highlight the difference between the impact of the
discount rate and other quantified sources of uncertainty, the bars below the frequency
distributions provide a symmetric representation of quantified variability in the SC-CO2
estimates for each discount rate. As illustrated by the figure, the assumed discount rate plays a
critical role in the ultimate estimate of the SC-CO2. This is because CO2 emissions today
continue to impact society far out into the future, so with a higher discount rate, costs that accrue
to future generations are weighted less, resulting in a lower estimate. As discussed in the
February 2021 TSD, there are other sources of uncertainty that have not yet been quantified and
are thus not reflected in these estimates.

In addition, the interim SC-CO2 estimates presented in Table 4-7 have a number of other
limitations. First, the current scientific and economic understanding of discounting approaches
suggests discount rates appropriate for intergenerational analysis in the context of climate change

4-29


-------
are likely to be less than 3 percent, near 2 percent or lower.42 Second, the IAMs used to produce
these interim estimates do not include all of the important physical, ecological, and economic
impacts of climate change recognized in the climate change literature and the science underlying
their "damage functions" - i.e., the core parts of the IAMs that map global mean temperature
changes and other physical impacts of climate change into economic (both market and
nonmarket) damages - lags behind the most recent research. For example, limitations include the
incomplete treatment of catastrophic and non-catastrophic impacts in the integrated assessment
models, their incomplete treatment of adaptation and technological change, the incomplete way
in which inter-regional and intersectoral linkages are modeled, uncertainty in the extrapolation of
damages to high temperatures, and inadequate representation of the relationship between the
discount rate and uncertainty in economic growth over long time horizons. Likewise, the
socioeconomic and emissions scenarios used as inputs to the models do not reflect new
information from the last decade of scenario generation or the full range of projections.

The modeling limitations do not all work in the same direction in terms of their influence
on the SC-CO2 estimates. However, as discussed in the February 2021 TSD, the IWG has
recommended that, taken together, the limitations suggest that the interim SC-CO2 estimates
used in this proposed action likely underestimate the damages from CO2 emissions. EPA concurs
that the values used in this action conservatively underestimate the action's climate disbenefits.
In particular, the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) Fourth Assessment Report
(IPCC 2007), which was the most current IPCC assessment available at the time when the IWG
decision over the ECS input was made, concluded that SC-CO2 estimates "very
likely.. .underestimate the damage costs" due to omitted impacts. Since then, the peer-reviewed
literature has continued to support this conclusion, as noted in the IPCC's Fifth Assessment
report (IPCC 2014) and other recent scientific assessments.43 These assessments confirm and
strengthen the science, updating projections of future climate change and documenting and
attributing ongoing changes. For example, sea level rise projections from the IPCC's Fourth

42	Interagency Working Group on Social Cost of Greenhouse Gases (IWG). 2021. Technical Support Document:
Social Cost of Carbon, Methane, and Nitrous Oxide Interim Estimates under Executive Order 13990. February.
United States Government. Available at: .

43	Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). 2014. Climate Change 2014: Synthesis Report.

Contribution of Working Groups I, II and III to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental
Panel on Climate Change [Core Writing Team, R.K. Pachauri and L.A. Meyer (eds.)]. IPCC, Geneva,

Switzerland, 151 pp.

4-30


-------
Assessment report ranged from 18 to 59 centimeters by the 2090s relative to 1980-1999, while
excluding any dynamic changes in ice sheets due to the limited understanding of those processes
at the time.44'45'46'47'48'49'50'51 A decade later, the Fourth National Climate Assessment projected a
substantially larger sea level rise of 30 to 130 centimeters by the end of the century relative to
2000, while not ruling out even more extreme outcomes.52 The February 2021 TSD briefly
previews some of the recent advances in the scientific and economic literature that the IWG is
actively following and that could provide guidance on, or methodologies for, addressing some of
the limitations with the interim SC-CO2 estimates. The IWG is currently working on a
comprehensive update of the SC-GHG estimates taking into consideration recommendations
from the National Academies of Sciences, Engineering and Medicine, recent scientific literature,
and public comments received on the February 2021 TSD.

44IPCC, 2007. Fourth Assessment Report, .

45	Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). 2018. Global Warming of 1.5°C. An IPCC Special
Report on the impacts of global warming of 1.5°C above pre-industrial levels and related global
greenhouse gas emission pathways, in the context of strengthening the global response to the threat of
climate change, sustainable development, and efforts to eradicate poverty [Masson-Delmotte, V., P.

Zhai, H.-O. Portner, D. Roberts, J. Skea, P.R. Shukla, A. Pirani, W. Moufouma-Okia, C. Pean, R. Pidcock, S.
Connors, J.B.R. Matthews, Y. Chen, X. Zhou, M.I. Gomis, E. Lonnoy, T. Maycock, M. Tignor, and T.

Waterfield (eds.)].

46	Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). 2019a. Climate Change and Land: an IPCC special
report on climate change, desertification, land degradation, sustainable land management, food
security, and greenhouse gas fluxes in terrestrial ecosystems [P.R. Shukla, J. Skea, E. Calvo Buendia, V.
Masson-Delmotte, H.-O. Portner, D. C. Roberts, P. Zhai, R. Slade, S. Connors, R. vanDiemen, M. Ferrat, E.
Haughey, S. Luz, S. Neogi, M. Pathak, J. Petzold, J. Portugal Pereira, P. Vyas, E. Huntley, K. Kissick, M.
Belkacemi, J. Malley, (eds.)].

47	Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). 2019b. IPCC Special Report on the Ocean and
Cryosphere in a Changing Climate [H.-O. Portner, D.C. Roberts, V. Masson-Delmotte, P. Zhai, M. Tignor,
E. Poloczanska, K. Mintenbeck, A. Alegria, M. Nicolai, A. Okem, J. Petzold, B. Rama, N.M. Weyer (eds.)].

48	U.S. Global Change Research Program (USGCRP). 2016. The Impacts of Climate Change on Human Health
in the United States: A Scientific Assessment. Crimmins, A., J. Balbus, J.L. Gamble, C.B. Beard, J.E. Bell, D.
Dodgen, R.J. Eisen, N. Fann, M.D. Hawkins, S.C. Herring, L. Jantarasami, D.M. Mills, S. Saha, M.C. Sarofim,
J. Trtanj, and L. Ziska, Eds. U.S. Global Change Research Program, Washington, DC, 312 pp.
.

49	U.S. Global Change Research Program (USGCRP). 2018. Impacts, Risks, and Adaptation in the United
States: Fourth National Climate Assessment, Volume II [Reidmiller, D.R., C.W. Avery, D.R. Easterling, K.E.
Kunkel, K.L.M. Lewis, T.K. Maycock, and B.C. Stewart (eds.)]. U.S. Global Change Research Program,
Washington, DC, USA, 1515 pp. doi: 10.7930/NCA4.2018.

50	National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and Medicine (National Academies). 2016b. Attribution of
Extreme Weather Events in the Context of Climate Change. Washington, DC: The National Academies
Press, .

51	National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and Medicine (National Academies). 2019. Climate Change
and Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press, .

52	USGCRP. 2018. The Impacts of Climate Change on Human Health in the United States: A Scientific Assessment,
4th National.; doi:.

4-31


-------
Table 4-8 and Table 4-9 show the estimated global climate disbenefits from changes in
CO2 emissions expected to occur for the proposed action from 2026 to 2040. For each year,
EPA estimated the dollar value of the C02-related effects by applying the SC-CO2 estimates,
shown in Table 4-7, to the estimated changes in CO2 emissions in the corresponding year under
the proposed action.53 EPA calculated the present value (PV) and equivalent annualized value of
disbenefits (EAV) from the perspective of 2022 by discounting each year-specific value to the
year 2022 using the same discount rate used to calculate the SC-CO2.54

Table 4-8: Projected Discounted Global CO2 Disbenefits under the Proposed Amendments,

GACT 6B, 2026-2040 (millions 2019$)	

Discounted back to 2022

Year

5%
Average

3%
Average

2.50%
Average

3%

95th Percentile

2026

$0.4

$1.6

$2.4

$4.9

2027

$0.4

$1.7

$2.4

$5.0

2028

$0.4

$1.7

$2.5

$5.1

2029

$0.4

$1.7

$2.5

$5.2

2030

$0.4

$1.8

$2.5

$5.3

2031

$0.4

$1.8

$2.6

$5.4

2032

$0.4

$1.8

$2.6

$5.5

2033

$0.4

$1.9

$2.7

$5.6

53 CO2 emissions increases above the baseline as a result of the modeled policy are first expected in 2025, as control
technologies applied in response to the final rule first begin operation in that year, and those emissions increases
are expected to remain at that level afterwards, according to the cost analysis for this rule.

54According to OMB's Circular A-4 (2003), an "analysis should focus on benefits and costs that accrue to citizens
and residents of the United States", and international effects should be reported separately. Circular A-4 also
reminds analysts that "[different regulations may call for different emphases in the analysis, depending on the
nature and complexity of the regulatory issues." To correctly assess the total climate damages to U.S. citizens and
residents, an analysis must account for impacts that occur within U.S. borders, climate impacts occurring outside
U.S. borders that directly and indirectly affect the welfare of U.S. citizens and residents, how U.S. GHG
mitigation activities affect mitigation activities by other countries, and spillover effects from climate action
elsewhere. The SC-GHG estimates used in regulatory analysis under revoked E.O. 13783 were an approximation
of the climate damages occurring within U.S. borders only (e.g., $7/mtC02 (2016$) and $9/mtC02 using a 3%
discount rate for emissions occurring in 2025). Applying the same estimate (based on a 3% discount rate) to the
CO2 emission reduction expected under the finalized option in this final rule would yield benefits from climate
impacts within U.S borders of $0.2 million (2016$) in 2025. However, as discussed at length in the February
2021 TSD, estimates focusing on the climate impacts occurring solely within U.S. borders are an underestimate of
the benefits of CO2 mitigation accruing to U.S. citizens and residents, as well as being subject to a considerable
degree of uncertainty due to the manner in which they are derived. In particular, the estimates developed under
revoked E.O. 13783 did not capture significant regional interactions, spillovers, and other effects and so are
incomplete underestimates. The U.S. District Court for the Northern District of California found that by omitting
such impacts, those "interim domestic" estimates "fail[ed] to consider.. .important aspect[s] of the problem" and
departed from the "best science available" as reflected in the global estimates. California v. Bernhardt, 472 F.
Supp. 3d 573, 613-14 (N.D. Cal. 2020). EPA continues to center attention in this regulatory analysis on the global
measures of the SC-GHG as the appropriate estimates and as necessary for all countries to use to achieve an
efficient allocation of resources for emissions reduction on a global basis, and so benefit the U.S. and its citizens.

4-32


-------
2034

$0.4

$1.9

$2.7

$5.7

2035

$0.3

$1.9

$2.7

$5.8

2036

$0.3

$2.0

$2.8

$5.9

2037

$0.3

$2.0

$2.8

$6.0

2038

$0.3

$2.0

$2.8

$6.1

2039

$0.3

$2.1

$2.9

$6.2

2040

$0.3

$2.1

$2.9

$6.3

PV

$5.4

$28

$40

$84

EAV

$0.5

$2.3

$3.2

$7.0

Note: Climate disbenefits are based on changes (reductions) in CO2 emissions and are calculated using four different estimates of
the social cost of carbon (SC-CO2) (model average at 2.5 percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount rates; 95th percentile at 3
percent discount rate). We emphasize the importance and value of considering the disbenefits calculated using all four SC-CO2
estimates. As discussed in the Technical Support Document: Social Cost of Carbon, Methane, and Nitrous Oxide Interim
Estimates under Executive Order 13990 (IWG 2021), a consideration of climate benefits calculated using discount rates below 3
percent, including 2 percent and lower, are also warranted when discounting intergenerational impacts.

4-33


-------
Table 4-9: Projected Discounted Global CO2 Benefits under the Proposed Amendments,
NSPS XX, 2026-2040 (millions 2019$)	

Discounted back to 2022

Year

5%
Average

3%
Average

2.50%
Average

3%

95th Percentile

2026

$0.02

$0.09

$0.13

$0.27

2027

$0.03

$0.11

$0.17

$0.34

2028

$0.03

$0.14

$0.20

$0.42

2029

$0.04

$0.17

$0.24

$0.50

2030

$0.04

$0.19

$0.28

$0.58

2031

$0.05

$0.22

$0.32

$0.67

2032

$0.05

$0.25

$0.36

$0.75

2033

$0.05

$0.28

$0.40

$0.85

2034

$0.06

$0.31

$0.44

$0.94

2035

$0.06

$0.35

$0.49

$1.04

2036

$0.06

$0.38

$0.53

$1.14

2037

$0.07

$0.41

$0.58

$1.24

2038

$0.07

$0.45

$0.63

$1.35

2039

$0.07

$0.48

$0.67

$1.46

2040

$0.08

$0.52

$0.72

$1.57

PV

$0.78

$4.4

$6.2

$13.1

EAV

$0.08

$0.37

$0.50

$1.10

Note: Climate disbenefits are based on changes (reductions) in CO2 emissions and are calculated using four different estimates of
the social cost of carbon (SC-CO2) (model average at 2.5 percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount rates; 95th percentile at 3
percent discount rate). We emphasize the importance and value of considering the disbenefits calculated using all four SC-CO2
estimates. As discussed in the Technical Support Document: Social Cost of Carbon, Methane, and Nitrous Oxide Interim
Estimates under Executive Order 13990 (IWG 2021), a consideration of climate benefits calculated using discount rates below 3
percent, including 2 percent and lower, are also warranted when discounting intergenerational impacts.

The climate disbenefits associated with the additional CO2 emissions generated as a result
of the requirements of the proposed action are therefore $32 million in 2022 PV ($2.6 million
EAV) at a 3 percent discount rate, and range from $6.1 million PV (.6 million EAV) at a 2.5
percent discount rate to $96 million PV ($8.0 million EAV) at a 3 percent discount rate (95th
percentile), all in 2019$.55 These disbenefits are estimated for 2026-2040, 15 years starting from
the first year of full implementation of both GACT 6B and NSPS XX (3 years after the effective
date) using the interim global social cost of carbon (SC-CO2) for 2026-2040 as shown in Table

55 In order to calculate these values, it is necessary to convert tons (short) of emissions to metric tons. These values
may be converted to $/short ton using the conversion factor 0.90718474 metric tons per short ton for application
to the short ton CO2 emissions impacts provided in this action. Hence, 32,910 short tons of emissions become
29,855 metric tons (tonnes) of emissions.

4-34


-------
4 - 7,56-57-58 The climate disbenefits are less than 7 percent of the monetized long-term health
benefits lower bound estimate even at the 3 percent (95th percentile), the discount rate yielding
the highest climate disbenefit estimate. At a discount rate of 3 percent (model average), the
climate disbenefits are less than 3 percent of the monetized long-term health benefits. Thus, the
monetized climate disbenefits are relatively small when compared to the monetized health
benefits.

CsJ

o

E

(J)

o
o
d

5% Average = $18

i
i
i
i

03

3% Average = $57

2.5% Average = $83

3%
95th Pet.

: $174

i

Steam

BBBBbhboi

IBQQQQiLbu

Discount Rate

O 5.0%
3.0%
2.5%

~
o

> 5th - 95'" Percentile
i , of Simulations

I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I

200 220 240 260 280 300



I I I I I I I I I I I I
0 20 40

I I I I I I
60 80

I I I I I I I I
100 120

"TTT
140

I I I I I I I I
160 180

Social Cost of Carbon in 2030 [2016$ / metric ton C02]

Figure 4-1: Social Cost of Carbon in 2030 [2016$ / metric ton CO2]

56	These SC-CO2 values are stated in $/metric ton CO2 and rounded to the nearest dollar. Such a conversion does not
change the underlying methodology, nor does it change the meaning of the SC-CO2 estimates. For both metric and
short tons denominated SC-CO2 estimates, the estimates vary depending on the year of CO2 emissions and are
defined in real terms, i.e., adjusted for inflation using the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) implicit price deflator.

57	To account for ethical considerations of future generations and potential uncertainty in the discount rate over long
time horizons, US OMB 's Circular A-4 suggests "further sensitivity analysis using a lower but positive discount
rate in addition to calculating net benefit using discount rates of 3 and 7 percent" (page 36) and notes that research
from the 1990s suggests intergenerational rates "from 1 to 3 percent per annum" (OMB, 2003). We consider the
uncertainty in this key assumption by calculating the domestic SC-CO2 based on a 2.5 percent discount rate, in
addition to the 3 and 7 percent used in the main analysis. Based on a 2.5 percent discount rate, the domestic
climate disbenefits of the final action in 2025 is $6 million in 2019$, with a value of $10/metric ton applied to
generate the estimate. Additional discussion of discounting and other quantified sources of uncertainty is provided
in the RIA for the ACE rule promulgated in 2019.

58	In addition to requiring reporting of domestic impacts. Circular A-4 states that when an agency "evaluate[s] a
regulation that is likely to have effects beyond the borders of the United States, these effects should be reported
separately" (page 15). This guidance is relevant to the valuation of damages from CO2 and other GHGs, given that
GHGs contribute to damages around the world independent of the country in which they are emitted.

4-35


-------
4.7 Total Monetized Benefits

Table 4-10 through Table 4-13 present a summary of monetized benefits for the proposed
amendments to GACT 6B and MACT R, and proposed NSPS XX both individually and
cumulatively. Net benefits in each table are calculated as health benefits minus climate
disbenefits. Benefits related to both short- and long-term exposure to ozone are estimated. Tables
presenting benefits list both estimates, with short-term benefits listed first. A complete discussion
of benefits relative to costs appears in Chapter 6.

4-36


-------
Table 4-10: Summary of Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits PV/EAV for GACT 6B, 2026-2040, (million 2019$)

Proposal	Less Stringent Alternative	More Stringent Alternative

3%

PV

EAV

PV

EAV

PV

EAV



$184 (ST)

$15(ST)

$52 (ST)

$4.4 (ST)

$228(ST)

$19(ST)

Health Benefits

and

and

and

and

and

and



$1,500 (LT)

$126 (LT)

$427(LT)

$36 (LT)

$1,900 (LT)

$160 (LT)

Climate Disbenefits

$28

$2.3

$28

$2.3

$28

$2.4



$160 (ST)

$13 (ST)

$24 (ST)

$2.1 (ST)

$200 (ST)

$17(ST)

Net Benefits

and

and

and

and

and

and



$1,500 (LT)

$120 (LT)

$400 (LT)

$34 (LT)

$1,900 (LT)

$160 (LT)

7%

$111(ST)

$12 (ST)

$32 (ST)

$3.5 (ST)

$137 (ST)

$15 (ST)

Health Benefits

and

and

and

and

and

and



$900 (LT)

$99 (LT)

$256 (LT)

$28 (LT)

$1,100 (LT)

$120 (LT)

Climate Disbenefits (3%)

$28

$2.3

$28

$2.3

$28

$2.4



$83 (ST)

$9.7 (ST)

$4.0 (ST)

$1.2 (ST)

$110 (ST)

$13(ST)

Net Benefits

and

and

and

and

and

and



$872 (LT)

$97 (LT)

$230 (LT)

$26 (LT)

$1,070 (LT)

$120 (LT)

Note: Monetized benefits include ozone related health benefits associated with reductions in VOC emissions. The health benefits are associated with several
point estimates and are presented at real discount rates of 3 and 7 percent for both short- (ST) and long-term (LT) benefits. The two benefits estimates are
separated by the word "and" to signify that they are two separate estimates. The estimates do not represent lower- and upper-bound estimates. Benefits from HAP
reductions and VOC reductions outside of the ozone season remain unmonetized and are thus not reflected in the table. The unmonetized effects also include
disbenefits resulting from a secondary increase in NO2, SO2, and CO emissions. Please see Section 4.6 for more discussion of the climate disbenefits.

Climate disbenefits are based on changes (increases) in CO2 emissions and are calculated using four different estimates of the social cost of carbon (SC-CO2)
(model average at 2.5 percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount rates; 95th percentile at 3 percent discount rate). For the presentational purposes of this table, we
show the disbenefits associated with the average SC-CO2 at a 3 percent discount rate, but the Agency does not have a single central SC-CO2 point estimate. We
emphasize the importance and value of considering the disbenefits calculated using all four SC-CO2 estimates; please see Table 4-8 for the full range of SC-CO2
estimates. As discussed in Chapter 4, a consideration of climate disbenefits calculated using discount rates below 3 percent, including 2 percent and lower, is also
warranted when discounting intergenerational impacts. The costs included in estimates of net benefits in this table are 2026 annual estimates. Rows may not
appear to add correctly due to rounding.

4-37


-------
Table 4-11: Summary of Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits PV/EAV for MAC ! R, 2026-2040, (million 2019$)

	Proposal	Less Stringent Alternative	More Stringent Alternative

3%

PV

EAV

PV

EAV

PV

EAV



$9.9 (ST)

$.83 (ST)

$2.1 (ST)

$.18 (ST)

$12 (ST)

$1.0 (ST)

Health Benefits

and

and

and

and

and

and



$81 (LT)

$6.8 (LT)

$17 (LT)

$1.4 (LT)

$98 (LT)

$8.2 (LT)

Climate Disbenefits

$0

$0

$0

$0

$0

$0



$9.9 (ST)

$.83 (ST)

$2.1 (ST)

$.18 (ST)

$12 (ST)

$1.0 (ST)

Net Benefits

and

and

and

and

and

and



$81 (LT)

$6.8 (LT)

$17 (LT)

$1.4 (LT)

$98 (LT)

$8.2 (LT)

7%















$5.6 (ST)

$0.65 (ST)

$1.3 (ST)

$0.14 (ST)

$7.2 (ST)

$0.8 (ST)

Health Benefits

and

and

and

and

and

and



$48 (LT)

$5.3 (LT)

$10 (LT)

$1.1 (LT)

$59 (LT)

$6.5 (LT)

Climate Disbenefits (3%)

$0

$0

$0

$0

$0

$0



$5.6 (ST)

$0.65 (ST)

$1.3 (ST)

$0.14 (ST)

$7.2 (ST)

$0.8 (ST)

Net Benefits

and

and

and

and

and

and



$48 (LT)

$5.3 (LT)

$10 (LT)

$1.1 (LT)

$59 (LT)

$6.5 (LT)

Note: Monetized benefits include ozone related health benefits associated with reductions in VOC emissions. The health benefits are associated with several
point estimates and are presented at real discount rates of 3 and 7 percent for both short- (ST) and long-term (LT) benefits. The two benefits estimates are
separated by the word "and" to signify that they are two separate estimates. The estimates do not represent lower- and upper-bound estimates. Benefits from HAP
reductions and VOC reductions outside of the ozone season remain unmonetized and are thus not reflected in the table. The unmonetized effects also include
disbenefits resulting from a secondary increase in NO2, SO2, and CO emissions. Please see Section 4.6 for more discussion of climate disbenefits. Benefits
(incorporating disbenefits) include those related to public health and climate. The health benefits are associated with several point estimates and are presented at
real discount rates of 3 and 7 percent for both short- (ST) and long-term (LT) benefits. Climate disbenefits are based on changes (increases) in CO2 emissions and
are calculated using four different estimates of the social cost of carbon (SC-CO2) (model average at 2.5 percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount rates; 95th
percentile at 3 percent discount rate). For the presentational purposes of this table, we show the disbenefits associated with the average SC-CO2 at a 3 percent
discount rate, but the Agency does not have a single central SC-CO2 point estimate. We emphasize the importance and value of considering the disbenefits
calculated using all four SC-CO2 estimates; please see Table 4-8 for the full range of SC-CO2 estimates. As discussed in Chapter 4, a consideration of climate
disbenefits calculated using discount rates below 3 percent, including 2 percent and lower, is also warranted when discounting intergenerational impacts. The
costs included in the net benefits presented in this table are 2026 annual estimates. Rows may not appear to add correctly due to rounding.

4-38


-------
Table 4-12: Summary of Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits PV/EAV for NSPS XXa, 2026-2040, (million 2019$)

Proposal	Less Stringent Alternative	More Stringent Alternative

	3%	PV	EAV	PV	EAV	PV	EAV

$29 (ST)	$2.4 (ST)	$2.4 (ST)	$0.20 (ST)	$29 (ST)	$2.4 (ST)

Health Benefits	and	and	and	and	and	and

$240 (LT)	$20 (LT)	$20 (LT)	$1.6 (LT)	$240 (LT)	$20 (LT)

Climate Disbenefits	$4.4	$0.37	$4.4	$0.37	$4.4	$0.37

$25 (ST) $2.0 (ST) ($1.5) (ST) ($0.13) (ST) $25 (ST) $2.1 (ST)
Net Benefits and and and and and and
	$240 (LT)	$20 (LT)	$16 (LT)	$1.3 (LT)	$240 (LT)	$20 (LT)

7%

$16 (ST)	$1.8 (ST)	$1.3 (ST)	$0.15 (ST)	$16 (ST)	$1.8 (ST)

Health Benefits and	and	and	and	and	and

$130 (LT)	$15 (LT)	$11 (LT)	$1.2 (LT)	$130 (LT)	$15 (LT)

Climate Disbenefits (3%) $4.4	$0.37	$4.4	$0.37	$4.4	$0.37

$12 (ST)	$1.4 (ST)	$(2.7) (ST)	$(0.18) (ST)	$12 (ST)	$1.5 (ST)
Net Benefits and	and	and	and	and and
	$130 (LT)	$15 (LT)	$7.0 (LT)	$0.87(LT)	$130 (LT)	$15 (LT)

Note: Monetized benefits include ozone related health benefits associated with reductions in VOC emissions. The health benefits are associated with several point
estimates and are presented at real discount rates of 3 and 7 percent for both short- (ST) and long-term (LT) benefits. The two benefits estimates are separated by
the word "and" to signify that they are two separate estimates. The estimates do not represent lower- and upper-bound estimates. Benefits from HAP reductions
and VOC reductions outside of the ozone season remain unmonetized and are thus not reflected in the table. The unmonetized effects also include disbenefits
resulting from a secondary increase in NO2, SO2, and CO emissions. Please see Section 4.6 for more discussion of climate disbenefits. Benefits (incorporating
disbenefits) include those related to public health and climate. The health benefits are associated with several point estimates and are presented at real discount
rates of 3 and 7 percent for both short- (ST) and long-term (LT) benefits. Climate disbenefits are based on changes (increases) in CO2 emissions and are
calculated using four different estimates of the social cost of carbon (SC-CO2) (model average at 2.5 percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount rates; 95th
percentile at 3 percent discount rate). For the presentational purposes of this table, we show the disbenefits associated with the average SC-CO2 at a 3 percent
discount rate, but the Agency does not have a single central SC-CO2 point estimate. We emphasize the importance and value of considering the disbenefits
calculated using all four SC-CO2 estimates; please see Table 4-8 for the full range of SC-CO2 estimates. As discussed in Chapter 4, a consideration of climate
disbenefits calculated using discount rates below 3 percent, including 2 percent and lower, is also warranted when discounting intergenerational impacts. Rows
may not appear to add correctly due to rounding.

4-39


-------
Table 4-13: Summary of Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits PV/EAV for All Rules, 2026-2040, (million 2019$)



Proposal



Less Stringent Alternative

More Stringent Alternative

3%

PV

EAV

PV

EAV

PV

EAV

Health Benefits
Climate Disbenefits
Net Benefits

$220 (ST)

and
$1,800 (LT)

$32
$190(ST)

and
$1,800 (LT)

$18(ST)

and
$150 (LT)

$2.7
$15(ST)

and
$150 (LT)

$57 (ST)

and
$460 (LT)

$32
$25 (ST)

and
$430 (LT)

$4.7 (ST)

and
$39 (LT)

$2.7
$2.0 (ST)

and
$36 (LT)

$270 (ST)

and
$2,200 (LT)

$32
$240 (ST)

and
$2,200 (LT)

$23 (ST)

and
$180 (LT)

$2.7
$20 (ST)

and
$180 (LT)

7%

Health Benefits
Climate Disbenefits (3%)
Net Benefits

$130 (ST)

and
$1,100 (LT)

$32
$100(ST)

and
$970 (LT)

$15(ST)

and
$120 (LT)

$2.7
$12 (ST)

and
$110 (LT)

$34 (ST)

and
$280 (LT)

$32
$2.0 (ST)

and
$2500 (LT)

$3.7 (ST)

and
$31 (LT)

$2.7
$1.0 (ST)

and
$28 (LT)

$160 (ST)

and
$1,300 (LT)

$32
$130 (ST)

and
$1,300 (LT)

$18 (ST)

and
$140 (LT)

$2.7
$15(ST)

and
$140 (LT)

Note: Monetized benefits include ozone related health benefits associated with reductions in VOC emissions. The health benefits are associated with several
point estimates and are presented at real discount rates of 3 and 7 percent for both short- (ST) and long-term (LT) benefits. The two benefits estimates are
separated by the word "and" to signify that they are two separate estimates. The estimates do not represent lower- and upper-bound estimates. Benefits from HAP
reductions and VOC reductions outside of the ozone season remain unmonetized and are thus not reflected in the table. The unmonetized effects also include
disbenefits resulting from a secondary increase in NO2, SO2, and CO emissions. Please see Section 4.6 for more discussion of the climate disbenefits. Benefits
(incorporating disbenefits) include those related to public health and climate. The health benefits are associated with several point estimates and are presented at
real discount rates of 3 and 7 percent for both short- (ST) and long-term (LT) benefits. Climate disbenefits are based on changes (increases) in CO2 emissions and
are calculated using four different estimates of the social cost of carbon (SC-CO2) (model average at 2.5 percent, 3 percent, and 5 percent discount rates; 95th
percentile at 3 percent discount rate). For the presentational purposes of this table, we show the disbenefits associated with the average SC-CO2 at a 3 percent
discount rate, but the Agency does not have a single central SC-CO2 point estimate. We emphasize the importance and value of considering the disbenefits
calculated using all four SC-CO2 estimates; please see Table 4-8 for the full range of SC-CO2 estimates. As discussed in Chapter 4, a consideration of climate
disbenefits calculated using discount rates below 3 percent, including 2 percent and lower, is also warranted when discounting intergenerational impacts. The
costs included in the net benefits presented in this table are 2026 annual estimates. Rows may not appear to add correctly due to rounding.

4-40


-------
5 ECONOMIC IMPACT ANALYSIS AND DISTRIBUTIONAL ASSESSMENTS

5.1	Introduction

The proposed amendments to the NESHAP for Gasoline Distribution GACT 6B
constitute an economically significant action according to Executive Order 12866. As discussed
in the previous section, the emissions reductions projected under the action are projected to
produce substantial VOC health benefits. At the same time, the proposed amendments to GACT
6B are projected to result in environmental control expenditures by the Gasoline Distribution
sector to comply with the rule. The proposed amendments to the NESHAP for Gasoline
Distribution MACT R and proposed NSPS for Bulk Gasoline Terminals are not projected to be
economically significant, but they also are expected to result in VOC health benefits and
increased environmental control expenditures.

While the national level impacts demonstrate the proposed action is likely to lead to
substantial benefits and costs, the benefit-cost analysis does not speak directly to potential
economic and distributional impacts of the proposed rules, which may be important
consequences of the action. This section includes three sets of economic impact and
distributional analyses for each individual rule included in this proposal action directed toward
complementing the benefit-cost analysis and includes a partial equilibrium analysis of market
impacts, an analysis of potentially affected small entities, and employment impacts.

5.2	Economic Impact Analysis

To provide a measure of the market impacts of the proposed amendments to the
NESHAPs for Gasoline Distribution and proposed NSPS for Bulk Gasoline Terminals, EPA
developed a single-market, static partial equilibrium model of the market for gasoline in the
United States. The model does not consider imports or exports of gasoline. This should not
materially affect the analysis, as gasoline imports make up a very small portion of total
consumption and gasoline exports make up a relatively small portion of total production59 The

59 In 2019, imports of finished gasoline accounted for about 1% of U.S. gasoline consumption. See data from the
U.S. Energy Information Administration:

. The U.S. is a net exporter
of gasoline, with exports accounting for about 8% of U.S. production

(). Gasoline exports are seasonal
increasing during periods of lower U.S. demand (See:
).

5-1


-------
model also does not model linkages between the gasoline market and other energy markets. The
goal is to provide broad insights into national-level market impacts and social costs of the
proposed action. The analysis allows for an estimate of how the proposed regulation will affect
the price of gasoline and the quantity of gasoline consumed and identifies how social costs of the
proposed regulation are distributed across consumers and firms. Using the model, it is
straightforward to estimate the economic impacts of the amendments to GACT 6B and MACT R
and proposed NSPS XXa both separately and cumulatively. This analytical approach is
consistent with the Economic Impact Analysis conducted for the 2008 area source NESHAP
(EPA, 2008), which is the most recent regulatory action taken by EPA to reduce HAP emissions
from the gasoline distribution sector.

5.2,1 Description of Approach/Model/Framework

5.2.1.1 Gasoline Market Model

EPA used a static, single-market partial equilibrium analysis of a national gasoline
market to estimate the economic impacts of the proposed NESHAP amendments and proposed
NSPS XXa. The analysis builds on the engineering costs analysis presented earlier and uses
economic theory related to consumer and producer behavior to estimate changes in market
prices, quantities, and economic welfare.

The model assumes perfect competition in the market for gasoline. This assumption was
made in the partial-equilibrium analysis conducted for the Economic Impact Analysis of the
2008 area source NESHAP; given little evidence of structural changes in gasoline distribution
since 2008, maintaining the assumption is reasonable. Supply and demand for gasoline are
isoelastic.60 The model is defined by the following set of equations:

Qst = Ast * (Pt ~ cktYs

(1)

Qdi = ADt * Vt°

(2)

Qst = Qdi

(3)

60This is a simplifying assumption and is justifiable given the small increases to engineering cost on a per-unit basis
for each proposed rule considered in this RIA.

5-2


-------
where pt is price at time t, es and eD are the elasticity of supply and demand for gasoline,
Ast and ADt are supply and demand specific parameters, and ckt is a per-unit cost shifter at time
t for regulation k. Equations (1) and (2) define the supply and demand curves for gasoline, Qst
and Qot, respectively, and equation (3) defines equilibrium in the gasoline market.

The following steps are necessary to solve the model:

1.	Specify values for the elasticity parameters es and eD.

2.	Specify baseline values for prices and quantities for all t.

3.	Calibrate Ast and ADt by inverting the supply and demand equations given parameter
values, given baseline prices and quantities, and assuming ckt = 0 in the baseline for all

4.	Calculate ckt for the following policies: NSPS XXa, MACT R, GACT 6B, and "All,"
where All is the cumulative cost of NSPS XXa, MACT R, and GACT 6B.

5.	Solve for equilibrium for each policy and analysis year.

Equilibrium is solved for numerically using the software program GAMS. There is no
relationship between solutions in different years. The model can be characterized as a set of
single-period partial equilibrium models.

5.2.1.2 Model Baseline

This RIA seeks to compare the state of the market with and without the changes to NSPS
XX, MACT R, and GACT 6B in effect. EPA selected the years 2026-2040 as the baseline for the
market analysis. These years were chosen for consistency with the engineering cost analysis
presented previously. The Annual Energy Outlook 2021, compiled by the Energy Information
Administration, projects gasoline prices and consumption through 2050, and provides the
baseline price and quantity data for the analysis. For an overview of the model, see Table 5-1.

Table 5-1: Description of Gasoline Market Model	

k and t.

Geographic Scope
Product Groupings

Single gasoline market
Perfect competition

National

Firm/consumer behavior
Baseline gasoline price/quantity

See Table 5-2

Baseline years
Supply elasticity

0.29 (Coyle et al 2012)

2026-2040

5-3


-------
Demand elasticity

-0.31 (Levin et al 2017)

Table 5-2: AEO 2021 Baseline Gasoline Projections, 2026-2040

Year

Price
($2019/gallon)

Quantity
(billion gallons)

2026

2.50

130.88

2027

2.53

130.04

2028

2.59

129.24

2029

2.64

128.35

2030

2.76

127.59

2031

2.78

126.86

2032

2.83

126.21

2033

2.85

125.74

2034

2.89

125.40

2035

2.91

125.13

2036

2.95

124.84

2037

2.98

124.58

2038

3.02

124.37

2039

3.02

124.28

2040

3.07

124.24

Source: Energy Information Administration. Annual Energy Outlook 2021. Feb. 3, 2021.

5.2.1.3 Model Parameters

Economic theory suggests consumers will bear a higher share of economic welfare losses
if the supply of gasoline is more responsive to changes than is the demand for gasoline.
Numerous peer-reviewed studies generally agree that over short periods of time demand for
gasoline is price inelastic. A recent study by Levin et al. (2017) estimates short-run gasoline
demand elasticity to be between -0.27 and -0.35. EPA chose the midpoint of this range, -0.31, as
the primary choice for this market analysis. This is similar to recent estimates by Coglianese et
al. (2016) of -0.37 and Bento at al. (2009) of -0.35. A demand elasticity of -0.31 suggests that a
10 percent increase in the price of gasoline will lead to an approximately 3.1 percent reduction in
the quantity of gasoline demanded.

There is relatively less empirical work on the elasticity of gasoline supply. For this
analysis, EPA chose the short-run estimate of 0.29 from Coyle, DeBacker, and Prisinzano
(2012). This is close to the value of 0.24 used in the Economic Impact Analysis for the 2008
Gasoline Distribution Area Source NESHAP, which came from an estimate of supply elasticity

5-4


-------
for refined petroleum products (Considine, 2002). It is also consistent with applied work on the
incidence of gasoline taxes (Chouinard & Perloff, 2004), which suggests that the national
demand elasticity for gasoline and national supply elasticity for gasoline should be roughly
equal.

5.2,2 Economic Impact Results

5.2.2.1	Market-Level Results

Market-level impacts in the gasoline market caused by the proposed regulations are
projected to be small, with the bulk of the impacts caused by the proposed amendments to GACT
6B. All rules cumulatively are projected to increase the price of gasoline ($2019/gallon) by less
than a hundredth of a cent/gallon in each year from 2026-2040 (less than .003 percent), with
about 58 percent of the increase coming from proposed changes to GACT 6B. Further, the
quantity of gasoline consumed is projected to fall by less than .001 percent in each year from
2026-2040 when the impacts of all rules are included. The maximum fall in quantity is 1.1
million gallons in 2040, against a baseline projection of 124 billion gallons61. Given that a barrel
of crude oil produces about 20 gallons of gasoline62, this projection implies a reduction in crude
oil demand of up to 55,000 barrels in 2040. EIA projects crude oil consumption of approximately
6.4 billion barrel-of-oil equivalent (BOE) in 204063, so 55,000 barrels represents less than .001
percent of total demand for crude oil.

When considering the impacts of the less and more stringent alternative options, the
results are qualitatively similar, but slightly smaller in the former case and slightly greater in the
latter case. For tables of market impacts by year for each package of regulatory alternatives, see
Appendix A.

5.2.2.2	Welfare Change Estimates

Table 5-3, Table 5-4, and Table 5-5 below present the projected welfare impacts of each
rule in present value (PV) and equivalent annual value (EAV), using both a 3 percent and 7

61	As production adjusts to the new equilibrium, there could be changes to the emissions reductions expected under
the proposed amendments. Any such effects are likely to be small.

62	Energy Information Administration.
. Accessed 1/24/2022.

63	Energy Information Administration. Annual Energy Outlook 2021. Table 1: Total Energy Supply, Disposition,
and Price Summary. Reference Case.

5-5


-------
percent social discount rate, for the proposed options and the less/more stringent package of
alternatives. The bulk of the welfare impacts are caused by the proposed amendments to GACT
6B, which is not unexpected given the large proportion of compliance cost for this overall action
that is found with this rule, and for each rule the projected costs are substantially offset by cost
savings from product recovery.

Table 5-3: Welfare Impacts of Proposed Options, 2026-2040 (Discounted to 2022, million
2019$)	

Rule

MACTR

GACT 6B

NSPS XXa

All

3%

PV

EAV

7%

PV

EAV

Change In Consumer Surplus64	-$17.0	-$1.4	-$11.0	-$1.2

Change In Producer Surplus65	-$18.0	-$1.5	-$12.0	-$1.3

Change In Welfare with Credits66	-$23.0	-$1.9	-$16.0	-$1.7

Change in Welfare Without Credits67	-$34.0	-$2.9	-$23.0	-$2.6

Change In Consumer Surplus	-$69.0	-$5.8	-$47.0	-$5.2

Change In Producer Surplus	-$74.0	-$6.2	-$50.0	-$5.5

Change In Welfare with Credits	$65.0 $5.4	$44.0	$4.8

Change in Welfare Without Credits	-$140.0	-$12.0	-$98.0	-$11.0

Change In Consumer Surplus	-$20.0	-$1.7	-$13.0	-$1.4

Change In Producer Surplus	-$21.0	-$1.8	-$13.0	-$1.5

Change In Welfare with Credits	-$8.8	-$0.7	-$5.6	-$0.6

Change in Welfare Without Credits	-$41.0	-$3.4	-$26.0	-$2.9

Change In Consumer Surplus	-$110.0	-$8.9	-$71.0	-$7.8

Change In Producer Surplus	-$110.0	-$9.5	-$76.0	-$8.3

Change In Welfare with Credits	$33.0	$2.7	$23.0	$2.5

Change in Welfare Without Credits	-$220.0	-$18.0	-$150.0	-$16.0

64	Changes in consumer surplus are estimated from changes in prices and quantities using the following linear
approximation formula: ACS = -(AP * Qnew) + -5 * AP * AQ.

65	Changes in producer surplus are estimated from changes in prices and quantities using the following linear
approximation formula: APS = (AP - ck) * Qnew - .5 * AP * AQ.

66	Changes in welfare with product recovery credits included is calculated by adding total product recovery credits to
ACS + APS.

67	Changes in welfare without product recovery credits included is calculated as ACS + APS.

5-6


-------
Table 5-4: Welfare Impacts of Less Stringent Alternative Options, 2026-2040 (Discounted
to 2022, million 2019$)	

3%	7%

Kiue



PV

EAV

PV

EAV



Change In Consumer Surplus

-$12.0

-$1.0

-$8.3

-$0.9

MACTR

Change In Producer Surplus
Change In Welfare with Credits

-$12.0
-$13.0

-$1.5
-$1.9

-$8.8
-$15.0

-$1.0
-$1.7



Change in Welfare Without Credits

-$23.0

-$2.9

-$17.0

-$1.9



Change In Consumer Surplus

-$14.0

-$1.2

-$9.7

-$1.1

GACT 6B

Change In Producer Surplus
Change In Welfare with Credits

-$15.0
$27.0

-$1.3
$2.3

-$10.0
$18.0

-$1.1
$2.0



Change in Welfare Without Credits

-$29.0

-$2.5

-$20.0

-$2.2



Change In Consumer Surplus

-$2.8

-$0.2

-$1.7

-$0.2

NSPS XXa

Change In Producer Surplus
Change In Welfare with Credits

-$2.9
-$3.0

-$0.3
-$0.3

-$1.9
-$1.9

-$0.2
-$0.2



Change in Welfare Without Credits

-$5.7

-$0.5

-$3.6

-$0.4



Change In Consumer Surplus

-$29.0

-$2.4

-$20.0

-$2.2

All

Change In Producer Surplus

-$31.0

-$9.5

-$21.0

-$8.3

Change In Welfare with Credits

$1.2

$2.7

$1.0

$2.5



Change in Welfare Without Credits

-$60.0

-$18.0

-$41.0

-$16.0

5-7


-------
Table 5-5: Welfare Impacts of More Stringent Alternative Options, 2026-2040 (Discounted
to 2022, million 2019$)	

Rule

3%

7%

PV

EAV

PV

EAV

MACTR

GACT 6B

NSPS XXa

All

Change In Consumer Surplus
Change In Producer Surplus
Change In Welfare with Credits
Change in Welfare Without Credits

-$42.7
-$45.6
-$74.2
1.3

-$3.6
-$3.8
-$6.2
-$7.4

-$29.0
-$31.0
-$50.5
-$60.1

-$3.2
-$3.4
-$5.5
-$6.6

Change In Consumer Surplus	-$259.4	-$21.7	-$176.5	-$19.4

Change In Producer Surplus	-$277.2	-$23.2	-$188.7	-$20.7

Change In Welfare with Credits	-$285.8	-$23.9	-$194.5	-$21.4

Change in Welfare Without Credits	-$536.6	-$45.0	-$365.2	-$40.1

Change In Consumer Surplus	-$20.2	-$1.7	-$12.8	-$1.4

Change In Producer Surplus	-$21.6	-$1.8	-$13.7	-$1.5

Change In Welfare with Credits	-$9.3	-$0.8	-$5.9	-$0.7

Change in Welfare Without Credits	-$41.8	-$3.5	-$26.6	-$2.9

Change In Consumer Surplus	-$322.3	-$27.0	-$218.4 -$24.0

Change In Producer Surplus	-$344.4	-$28.9	-$233.4 -$25.6

Change In Welfare with Credits	-$369.3	-$30.9	-$250.9 -$27.5

Change in Welfare Without Credits	-$666.7	-$55.8	-$451.8 -$49.6

The national compliance cost estimates are often used to approximate the social cost of
the rule. However, in cases where the engineering costs of compliance are used to estimate social
cost, the burden of the regulation is typically measured as falling solely on the affected
producers, who experience a profit loss exactly equal to these cost estimates. Thus, the entire loss
is a change in producer surplus with no change (by assumption) in consumer surplus because no
changes in price and consumption are estimated. This is typically referred to as a "full-cost
absorption" scenario in which all factors of production are assumed to be fixed and firms are
unable to adjust their output levels when faced with additional costs.

In contrast, this market analysis builds on the engineering cost analysis and incorporates
economic theory related to producer and consumer behavior to estimate changes in market
conditions. Gasoline producers can make supply adjustments that will generally affect the market
environment in which they operate. As producers change levels of gasoline supply in response to
a regulation, consumers are typically faced with changes in prices that cause them to alter the
quantity they are willing to purchase. These changes in price and output from the market model

5-8


-------
are used to estimate the total surplus losses/gains for two types of stakeholders: gasoline
consumers and producers.

5.2.2.3 Limitations

Ultimately, the regulatory program will increase the costs of supplying gasoline to
consumers, and the model is designed to evaluate behavioral responses to this change in costs
within a market equilibrium setting. However, the results should be viewed with the following
three limitations in mind. First, the national competitive market assumption is clearly very strong
because the gasoline markets in this analysis are regional. Regional price and quantity impacts
could be different from the average impacts reported below if local market structures, production
costs, or demand conditions are substantially different from those used in this analysis. Second,
the model uses a market supply function and analyzes supply behavior at or near a single market
baseline equilibrium using a supply elasticity parameter. Therefore, it does not address facility-
level impacts such as closures or changes in employment. Although developing a facility-level
model could potentially provide these outputs, this type of model requires substantial amounts of
detailed data for individual facilities and a level of effort beyond the scope of this analysis.
Finally, we do not evaluate supply-side welfare losses by segments of the gasoline supply chain.
EPA relied on the cost-to-sales ratio analysis to make inferences about the relative impacts
across producers within this chain (see Section 5.3 below).

5.3 Small Business Impacts Analysis

The Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA) generally requires an agency to prepare a
regulatory flexibility analysis of any rule subject to notice and comment rulemaking
requirements under the Administrative Procedure Act or any other statute unless the agency
certifies that the rule will not have a significant economic impact on a substantial number of
small entities. Small entities include small businesses, small organizations, and small
governmental jurisdictions.

For purposes of assessing the impacts of this action on small entities, a small entity is
defined as: (1) a small business as defined by the Small Business Administration's (SBA)
regulations at 13 CFR 121.201; (2) a small governmental jurisdiction that is a government of a
city, county, town, school district or special district with a population of less than 50,000; and (3)

5-9


-------
a small organization that is any not-for-profit enterprise that is independently owned and
operated and is not dominant in its field. Businesses in the Gasoline Distribution source category
predominately have NAICS codes 424710 (Petroleum Bulk Stations and Terminals) and 486910
(Pipeline Transportation of Refined Petroleum Products). For the SBA small business size
standard definition for each NAICS classification, see below in Table 5-6.

Table 5-6: SBA Size Standards by NAICS Code	

NAICS
Codes

NAICS Industry Description

Size Standards
(in no. of employees)

424710

Petroleum Bulk Stations and Terminals

200

486910

Pipeline Transportation of Refined Petroleum
Products

1,500

Sources: U.S. Small Business Administration, Table of Standards, Effective August 19, 2019.
https://www.sba.gov/document/support--table-size-standards. Accessed December 12, 2021.

This analysis contains two sections: an analysis of potential impacts on small businesses
using a facility list constructed by EPA (Facility List, discussed in Section 2.2.3), and a
supplementary analysis using data collected by the US Census Bureau. Using the Facility List,
EPA conducted a cost-to-sales analysis to estimate the potential impacts of the proposed action.
The EPA prefers a "sales test" as the impact methodology in small entity analyses for
rulemakings as opposed to a "profits test", in which annualized compliance costs are calculated
as a share of profits68. This is consistent with guidance published by the U.S. Small Business
Administration (SBA) Office of Advocacy, which suggests that cost as a percentage of total
revenues is a metric for evaluating cost impacts on small entities relative to large entities69. This
is because revenues or sales data are commonly available for entities impacted by EPA
regulations and profits data are often private or misrepresent true profits earned by firms after
undertaking accounting and tax considerations.

While a "sales test" can provide some insight as to the economic impact of an action such
as this one, it assumes that the impacts of a rule are solely incident on a directly affected firm
(therefore, no impact to consumers of the affected product), or solely incident on consumers of
output directly affected by this action (therefore, no impact to companies that are producers of

68	More information on sales and profit tests as used in analyses done by U.S. EPA can be found in the Final
Guidance for EPA Rulewriters: Regulatory Flexibility Act as Amended by the Small Business Regulatory
Enforcement Fairness Act, November 2006, pp. 32-33.

69	U.S. SBA, Office of Advocacy. 2010. A Guide for Government Agencies, How to Comply with the Regulatory
Flexibility Act, Implementing the President's Small Business Agenda and Executive Order 13272.

5-10


-------
the affected product). Thus, an analysis such as this one is best viewed as providing insight on
the polar examples of economic impacts: maximum impact to either directly affected companies
or their consumers. A "sales test" analysis does not consider shifts in supply and demand curves
to reflect intermediate economic outcomes. For a partial equilibrium analysis of the economic
impacts of this action that attempts to parse impacts on consumers relative to producers, see 5.2.

5.3,1 Small Business National Overview

EPA constructed a facility list for the Gasoline Distribution source category. For
information on how this list was constructed, see Section 2.2.3. For the initial list of 1,838
facilities, EPA identified the ultimate parent company along with revenue and employment
information for 1,705 of these facilities using D&B Hoover's database. This included 118 major
source facilities owned by 41 ultimate parent companies, 1,587 area source facilities owned by
163 ultimate parent companies, and 12 facilities known to be subject to NSPS XX owned by 9
ultimate parent companies. In total, EPA identified 269 ultimate parent companies as owners of
the 1,705 facilities, of which 112 of these ultimate parent companies were identified as small
entities (counts of parent companies do not sum over rules due to some companies owning
facilities subject to multiple rules). Summary statistics for these ultimate parent companies are in

Table 5-7 below.

Table 5-7: Summary Statistics of Potentially Affected Entities

Rule

Size

No. of Ultimate Parent
Companies

Number of
Facilities

Mean Revenue
(million 2019$)

Median Revenue
(million 2019$)

MACT R

Small

2

2

$11

$11







Not Small

39

116

$40,000

$7,400

GACT 6B

Small

111

175

$96

$23



$22,000

$2,100



Not Small

152

1,412



Small

0

0

N/A

N/A

NSPS XX







Not Small

9

12

$61,000

$11,000

All

Small
Not Small

112
157

177
1,528

$95
$22,000

$22
$2,200

Source: EPA Gasoline Distribution Facility List and D&B Hoover's Database.

Only two small ultimate parent companies own a facility subject to MACT R or NSPS
XX. Based on this, it is unlikely that the proposed amendments to MACT R or the proposed
NSPS XXa could have a significant impact on a substantial number of small entities. However,
while a large majority of area-source facilities (89 percent) are owned by ultimate parent

5-11


-------
companies not classified as small by the SBA, a substantial number of the ultimate parent
companies that own area source gasoline distribution facilities are small entities (111 or 42
percent).

5.3.2 Small Entity Economic Impacts

5.3.2.1 Main Screening Analysis

Using the facility list discussed in the above section, EPA conducted cost-to-sales
analysis for the proposed action to screen small entities for potentially significant impacts. While
EPA could identify (at least in certain cases) when a facility was a pipeline breakout station or
pumping station, we could not determine for bulk distribution facilities which facilities were bulk
plants and which were bulk terminals. Because of this, EPA constructed "worst-case" total
annualized costs for each rule and facility. This consisted of constructing a total annualized cost
for each model plant and selecting the maximum for two categories of facility: "Plant or
Terminal," and "Breakout or Pumping Station." For a discussion of the model pants and the
engineering cost analysis performed for this action, see Chapter 3. The worst-case costs for each
rule and facility type are in Table 5-8 below.

Table 5-8: Worst-Case Costs by Model Plant	

Total Annualized Cost without „ . . . .. , ,, , . ,

Total Annualized Cost with

Rule	Facility Type	Product Recovery

($2019)

Product Recovery ($2019)

GACT6B	Bulk Plant or Terminal	$21,000	$9,700

Pipeline Breakout or Pumping Station	$330	$180

MACTR	Bulk Terminal	$19,000	$12,000

Pipeline Breakout Station	-$2,300	-$8,600

NSPSXXa	Bulk Terminal	$120,000	$40,000

The analysis proceeds as follows:

1.	Assign worst-case total annualized cost to each facility based on rule and facility type.

2.	Calculate total worst-case costs for each ultimate parent company by summing over a
rules and facilities.

3.	Calculate a cost-to-sales ratio (CSR) for each ultimate parent company.

5-12


-------
The results of this analysis for the proposed options are presented below. Table 5-9 shows the
distribution of costs for ultimate parent companies by rule. Table 5-10 and Table 5-11 below
show the distribution of CSRs by rule and the percentage of CSRs clearing 1 percent and 3
percent for each rule.

Table 5-9: Distribution of Estimated Compliance Costs by Rule and Size for Proposed
Options ($2019)	

Rule

Size No.

of Firms

Average Cost with

Average Cost without

Product Recovery

Product Recovery



Small

2

$12,000

$19,000

MACTR







Not Small

39

$11,000

$18,000



Small

111

$9,700

$21,000

GACT 6B







Not Small

152

$9,700

$21,000



Small

0

N/A

N/A

NSPS XXa











Not Small

9

$40,000

$120,000



Small

112

$9,700

$21,000

All







Not Small

157

$10,000

$22,000

Table 5-10: Compliance Cost-to-Sales Ratio Distributions for Small Entities, Proposed

Options















With Product Recovery

Without Product







Included

Recovery Included

Rule















Mean Maximum

Mean Maximum







CSR CSR

CSR CSR

MACTR



2

0.15% 0.23%

0.24% 0.36%

GACT 6B

No. of Small Entities

111

0.19% 3.06%

0.42% 6.75%

NSPS XXa



0

-

-

All

No. of Small Entities

112

0.19% 3.06%

0.42% 6.75%

5-13


-------
Table 5-11: Compliance Cost-to-Sales Ratio Thresholds for Small Entities - Proposed
Options	

, „ , . „	T i j j Without Product Recovery

With Product Recovery Included	T i j j

Rule

No. of Small % of Small No. of Small % of Small
Entities	Entities	Entities	Entities



No. of Small Entities

2

100.0%

2

100.0%

MACT R

Greater than 1%

0

0.0%

0

0.0%



Greater than 3%

0

0.0%

0

0.0%



No. of Small Entities

111

100.0%

111

100.0%

GACT 6B

Greater than 1%

6

5.4%

10

9.0%



Greater than 3%

1

0.9%

4

3.6%



No. of Small Entities

0

-

0

-

NSPS XXa

Greater than 1%

-

-

-

-



Greater than 3%

-

-

-

-



No. of Small Entities

112

100.0%

112

100.0%

All

Greater than 1%

6

5.4%

10

8.9%



Greater than 3%

1

0.9%

4

3.6%

Given the very low average CSR for small entities (both with and without product
recovery) and the low proportion of small entities with a CSR above 3 percent, it is unlikely that
the proposed changes to MACT R and GACT 6B or proposed NSPS XXa would have a
significant impact on a substantial number of small entities. Also, given the low (and in the case
of MACT R, negative) worst-case costs associated with pipeline facilities, it is clear that the
proposed action would not have a significant impact on a substantial number of small entities
owning pipeline facilities (although there are no such facilities on the list compiled by EPA).
Further, these CSRs are conservative and are likely to overstate the impact of the action on small
entities.

The above analysis has one main limitation: EPA's facility list does not provide complete
coverage of the Gasoline Distribution source category. Given this circumstance, it is possible
that the facility list is skewed towards larger entities (that would be easier to identify) in the
source category, in which case the above analysis could understate the impacts of the action on
small entities. This could be a particular problem in the case of bulk gasoline plants covered by
GACT 6B. This is less likely to be the case since the worst-case costs used above overstate costs

5-14


-------
for bulk plants. Also, this analysis does not take into account that the smallest bulk plants will be
exempt from the vapor balancing requirement due to not reaching a minimum throughput
threshold of 4,000 gallons per day. Assuming a throughput of 4,000 gallons per day, 200
operating days per year, and an average rack price of $1.82 (the 2019 average) would generate
$1,456,000 in revenue for the smallest bulk plants required to install loading controls. This is
more revenue than all small entities with a CSR greater than 3 percent, all but 4 small entities
with a CSR greater than 1 percent and would lead to a worst-case CSR of 1.44%. Still,
considering this possibility, we supplement the analysis below using Census data.

5.3.2.2 Supplementary Screening Analysis

The facility list compiled by EPA suggests that most of the small entities affected by the
proposed action are area sources. Further, given the facility list's gaps in coverage, it is possible
the list is skewed towards larger facilities. In this section, we investigate further the possibility
that the proposed amendments to GACT 6B could have a significant impact on small entities.

Table 5-12 below shows the number of firms and average sales for firms in various
employment groups tracked by the US Census Bureau. The table shows all employment groups
for which a firm could be classified as a small entity under SBA size standards. Note that this is a
conservatively high count of small entities in each group, since a firm may be owned by a larger
ultimate parent company with employment above the SBA threshold. There are 2,197 potential
small entities with NAICS classification 424710 based on this data.

This information is augmented by calculations of the cost necessary to hit a 1 percent or 3
percent CSR for a firm in each employment group with average sales, and the worst-case CSR
for a firm in the group with average sales under the proposed changes to GACT 6B. In the
smallest employment group (<5 employees), the worst-case cost without product recovery
included is less than half of that required to hit the 1 percent CSR threshold under the proposed
changes, and less than 1/6 of that required to cross the 3 percent CSR threshold. The average
worst-case CSR without product recovery in the smallest employment group is .48 percent and is
Vi of that or less in each larger employment group. Further, recall that the cost estimates used to
construct the worst-case CSRs are likely to overstate the costs of the proposed requirements for
small entities. This evidence strongly suggests that the proposed changes to GACT 6B will not
have a substantial impact on a significant number of small entities.

5-15


-------
In addition, we note that this action does not contain an unfunded mandate of $100
million or more as described in the Unfunded Mandates Reform Act, 2 U.S.C. 1531-1538, and
does not significantly or uniquely affect small governments. The action imposes no enforceable
duty on any state, local or tribal governments or the private sector.

5-16


-------
Table 5-12: NAICS 424710 -

Small Entity Impacts











Average Sales
($2019)





GACT 6B Worst-

GACT 6B Worst-Case

Size

Firms

1% CSR Threshold

3% CSR Threshold

Case CSR with

CSR without Product









Product Recovery

Recovery

<5 employees

508

$4,500,000

$45,000

$130,000

0.22%

0.48%

5-9 employees

415

$19,000,000

$190,000

$570,000

0.05%

0.11%

10-14 employees

267

$25,000,000

$250,000

$750,000

0.04%

0.09%

15-19 employees

144

$31,000,000

$310,000

$920,000

0.03%

0.07%

20-24 employees

121

$43,000,000

$430,000

$1,300,000

0.02%

0.05%

25-29 employees

83

$31,000,000

$310,000

$920,000

0.03%

0.07%

30-34 employees

65

$48,000,000

$480,000

$1,500,000

0.02%

0.04%

35-39 employees

60

$61,000,000

$610,000

$1,800,000

0.02%

0.04%

40-49 employees

92

$46,000,000

$460,000

$1,400,000

0.02%

0.05%

50-74 employees

115

$200,000,000

$2,000,000

$6,100,000

0.00%

0.01%

75-99 employees

76

$310,000,000

$3,100,000

$9,300,000

0.00%

0.01%

100-149 employees

83

$94,000,000

$940,000

$2,800,000

0.01%

0.02%

150-199 employees

57

$210,000,000

$2,100,000

$6,400,000

0.00%

0.01%

200-299 employees

69

$120,000,000

$1,200,000

$3,500,000

0.01%

0.02%

300-399 employees

27

$360,000,000

$3,600,000

$11,000,000

0.00%

0.01%

400-499 employees

15

$490,000,000

$4,900,000

$15,000,000

0.00%

0.00%

Source: US Census Bureau. County Business Patterns 2017 and Economic Census 2017.

5-17


-------
5.4 Employment Impact Analysis

This section presents a qualitative overview of the various ways that environmental
regulation can affect employment. Employment impacts of environmental regulations are
generally composed of a mix of potential declines and gains in different areas of the economy
over time. Regulatory employment impacts can vary across occupations, regions, and industries;
by labor and product demand and supply elasticities; and in response to other labor market
conditions. Isolating such impacts is a challenge, as they are difficult to disentangle from
employment impacts caused by a wide variety of ongoing, concurrent economic changes. The
EPA continues to explore the relevant theoretical and empirical literature and to seek public
comments in order to ensure that the way the EPA characterizes the employment effects of its
regulations is reasonable and informative.

Environmental regulation "typically affects the distribution of employment among
industries rather than the general employment level" (Arrow, et al., 1996). Even if impacts are
small after long-run market adjustments to full employment, many regulatory actions have
transitional effects in the short run (Office of Management and Budget, 2015). These movements
of workers in and out of jobs in response to environmental regulation are potentially important
and of interest to policymakers. Transitional job losses have consequences for workers that
operate in declining industries or occupations, have limited capacity to migrate, or reside in
communities or regions with high unemployment rates.

As indicated by the market analysis presented in Section 5.2, and the potential impacts on
firms owning Gasoline Distribution facilities in Section 5.3, the proposed requirements are likely
to cause only small shifts in gasoline consumption and prices. As a result, demand for labor
employed in gasoline distribution activities and associated industries, which we estimate is
approximately 66,000 employees based on 2017 Economic Census data as mentioned in Chapter
2, is unlikely to see large changes but might experience adjustments as there may be increases in
compliance-related labor requirements such as labor associated with the manufacture,
installation, and operation of pollution control equipment such as new or upgraded carbon
adsorbers and thermal combustors (e.g. oxidizers) , and monitors. In addition, there may be
changes in employment due to effects on output from directly regulated sectors and sectors that
consume gasoline. If gasoline price increases sufficiently as a result of this action, then revenues

5-18


-------
of firms directly regulated and those in gasoline-consuming sectors may fall and their
employment may potentially decline (though such changes should likely be small in light of the
estimated change in output price mentioned above). EPA estimates that facility-level
compliance with proposed monitoring, recordkeeping, and reporting (MRR) requirements will
necessitate approximately 49 full-time equivalent hours (FTE) per-year for the proposed GACT
6B amendments, 29 FTE per-year for the proposed MACT R amendments, and .33 FTE for the
proposed NSPS XXa after 5 years. Such proposed MRR requirements include additional
reporting for source tests by bulk gasoline terminals and a relative accuracy test audit (RATA)
for TOC monitors used at loading racks. For a discussion of the assumptions underlying these
calculations, see the Technical Memo on Monitoring (RTI, 2022). For this proposal, however,
we do not have the data and analysis available to quantify potential labor impacts beyond those
required for MRR compliance, although as explained, we expect those impacts to be relatively
small.

5-19


-------
6 COMPARISON OF BENEFITS AND COSTS

In this chapter, we present a comparison of the benefits and costs of this proposed action.
As explained in the previous chapters, all costs and benefits outlined in this RIA are estimated as
the change from the baseline, which reflects the requirements already promulgated. As stated
earlier in this RIA, there is no monetized estimate of the benefits for the HAP emission
reductions expected to occur as a result of this proposed action. We do present monetized
estimates for other impacts of this action, such as benefits from both short- and long-term
reduced exposure to ozone caused by VOC emissions reductions and disbenefits from increases
in CO2 emissions.

6.1 Results

As part of fulfilling analytical guidance with respect to E.O. 12866, EPA presents
estimates of the present value (PV) of the benefits and costs over the period 2026 to 2040. To
calculate the present value of the social net benefits of the proposed action, annual benefits and
costs are in 2019 dollars and are discounted to 2022 at 3 percent and 7 percent discount rates as
directed by OMB's Circular A-4. The EPA also presents the equivalent annualized value (EAV),
which represents a flow of constant annual values that would yield a sum equivalent to the PV.
The EAV represents the value of a typical cost or benefit for each year of the analysis, consistent
with the estimate of the PV, in contrast to year-specific estimates.

Tables 6-1 through Table 6-4 presents a summary of the monetized benefits, compliance
costs, and net benefits (including climate disbenefits) of each rule, and cumulatively, and the
more and less stringent alternatives for in terms of present value (PV) and equivalent annualized
value (EAV). Benefits related to both short- (ST) and long-term (LT) exposure to ozone are
estimated. Tables presenting benefits list both figures, with short-term benefits listed first.

6-1


-------
Table 6-1: Summary of Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits, Compliance Costs, and Net Benefits PV/EAV for
GACT 6B, 2026-2040 (million 2019$, discounted to 2022)	

Proposal	Less Stringent Alternative	More Stringent Alternative

3%

PV

EAV

PV

EAV

PV

EAV

Health Benefits
Climate Disbenefits(3%)

$184 (ST)

and
$1,500 (LT)
$28

$15 (ST)

and
$126 (LT)
$2.3

$52 (ST)

and
$427(LT)
$28

$4.4 (ST)

and
$36 (LT)
$2.3

$228 (ST)

and
$1,900 (LT)
$28

$19 (ST)

and
$160 (LT)
$2.4

Net Compliance Costs

($70)

($5)

($27)

($2)

$280

$24

Compliance Costs

$140

$12

$29

$3

$530

$45

Value of Product Recovery

$210

$17

$56

$5

$250

$21

Net Benefits

$230 (ST)
and
$1,500 (LT)

$18 (ST)

and
$130 (LT)

$50 (ST)

and
$430 (LT)

$4.1 (ST)

and
$36 (LT)

($80) (ST)

and
$1,600 (LT)

($7.4) (ST)

and
$130 (LT)

7%

Health Benefits

$111 (ST)

and
$900 (LT)

$12 (ST)

and
$99 (LT)

$32 (ST)

and
$256 (LT)

$3.5 (ST)

and
$28 (LT)

$137 (ST)

and
$1,100 (LT)

$15 (ST)

and
$120 (LT)

Climate Disbenefits (3%)

$28

$2.3

$28

$2.3

$28

$2.4

Net Compliance Costs

($42)

($5)

($18)

($2)

$190

$21

Compliance Costs

$98

$11

$20

$2

$360

$40

Value of Product Recovery

$140

$16

$38

$4

$170

$19

Net Benefits

$130 (ST)

and
$910(LT)

$15 (ST)

and
$100 (LT)

$20 (ST)

and
$250 (LT)

$3.2 (ST)

and
$28 (LT)

($81) (ST)

and
$880 (LT)

($8.4) (ST)

and
$97 (LT)

Note: Monetized benefits include ozone related health benefits associated with reductions in VOC emissions. The health benefits are associated with several point estimates and are presented at real
discount rates of 3 and 7 percent for both short- (ST) and long-term (LT) benefits. The two benefits estimates are separated by the word "and" to signify that they are two separate estimates. The
estimates do not represent lower- and upper-bound estimates. Benefits from HAP reductions and VOC reductions outside of the ozone season remain unmonetized and are thus not reflected in the table.
The unmonetized effects also include disbenefits resulting from a secondary increase in N02, S02, and CO emissions. Please see Section 4.6 for more discussion of the climate disbenefits. Benefits
(incorporating disbenefits) include those related to public health and climate. The health benefits are associated with several point estimates and are presented at real discount rates of 3 and 7 percent.
Climate disbenefits are based on changes (increases) in C02 emissions and are calculated using four different estimates of the social cost of carbon (SC-C02) (model average at 2.5 percent, 3 percent,
and 5 percent discount rates; 95 th percentile at 3 percent discount rate). For the presentational purposes of this table, we show the disbenefits associated with the average SC-C02 at a 3 percent discount
rate, but the Agency does not have a single central SC-C02 point estimate. We emphasize the importance and value of considering the disbenefits calculated using all four SC-C02 estimates; please see
Table 4-8 for the full range of SC-C02 estimates. As discussed in Chapter 4, a consideration of climate disbenefits calculated using discount rates below 3 percent, including 2 percent and lower, is also
warranted when discounting intergenerational impacts. The costs presented in this table are 2026 annual estimates. Net compliance costs are the compliance costs minus the value of product recovery
from compliance with the rule. Hence, net compliance costs are negative if the value of product recovery exceeds the compliance costs. Rows may not appear to add correctly due to rounding.

6-2


-------
Table 6-2: Summary of Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits, Compliance Costs, and Net Benefits PV/EAV for
MACT R, 2026-2040 (million 2019$, discounted to 2022)	

Proposal	Less Stringent Alternative	More Stringent Alternative

3%

PV

EAV

PV

EAV

PV

EAV



$9.9 (ST)

$.83 (ST)

$2.1 (ST)

$.18 (ST)

$12 (ST)

$1.0 (ST)

Health Benefits

and

and

and

and

and

and



$81 (LT)

$6.8 (LT)

$17 (LT)

$1.4 (LT)

$98 (LT)

$8.2 (LT)

Climate Disbenefits(3%)

$0

$0

$0

$0

$0

$0

Net Compliance Costs

$23

$2

$23

$2

$74

$6

Compliance Costs

$34

$3

$25

$2

$88

$7

Value of Product Recovery

$11

$1

$2.4

$0.2

$14

$1



($13)(ST)

($1.2) (ST)

($21) (ST)

($1.8) (ST)

($62) (ST)

($5.0) (ST)

Net Benefits

and

and

and

and

and

and



$58 (LT)

$4.8 (LT)

($6.0) (LT)

($0.6) (LT)

$24 (LT)

$2.2 (LT)

7%

$5.6 (ST)

$0.65 (ST)

$1.3 (ST)

$0.14 (ST)

$7.2 (ST)

$0.8 (ST)

Health Benefits

and

and

and

and

and

and



$48 (LT)

$5.3 (LT)

$10 (LT)

$1.1 (LT)

$59 (LT)

$6.5 (LT)

Climate Disbenefits (3%)

$0

$0

$0

$0

$0

$0

Net Compliance Costs

$15

$2

$15

$2

$51

$6

Compliance Costs

$23

$3

$17

$2

$60

$7

Value of Product Recovery

$8

$1

$1.6

$0.2

$9

$1

Net Benefits

($9.4) (ST)

and
$33 (LT)

($1.4) (ST)

and
$3.3 (LT)

($14) (ST)

and
($5.0) (LT)

($1.9) (ST)

and
($0.9) (LT)

($44) (ST)

and
$8.0 (LT)

($5.2) (ST)

and
$0.5 (LT)

Note: Monetized benefits include ozone related health benefits associated with reductions in VOC emissions. The health benefits are associated with several point estimates and are presented at real
discount rates of 3 and 7 percent for both short- (ST) and long-term (LT) benefits. The two benefits estimates are separated by the word "and" to signify that they are two separate estimates. The
estimates do not represent lower- and upper-bound estimates. Benefits from HAP reductions and VOC reductions outside of the ozone season remain unmonetized and are thus not reflected in the table.
The unmonetized effects also include disbenefits resulting from a secondary increase in N02, S02, and CO emissions. Please see Section 4.6 for more discussion of the climate disbenefits. Benefits
(incorporating disbenefits) include those related to public health and climate. The health benefits are associated with several point estimates and are presented at real discount rates of 3 and 7 percent.
Climate disbenefits are based on changes (increases) in C02 emissions and are calculated using four different estimates of the social cost of carbon (SC-C02) (model average at 2.5 percent, 3 percent,
and 5 percent discount rates; 95th percentile at 3 percent discount rate). For the presentational purposes of this table, we show the disbenefits associated with the average SC-C02 at a 3 percent discount
rate, but the Agency does not have a single central SC-C02 point estimate. We emphasize the importance and value of considering the disbenefits calculated using all four SC-C02 estimates; please see
Table 4-8 for the full range of SC-C02 estimates. As discussed in Chapter 4, a consideration of climate disbenefits calculated using discount rates below 3 percent, including 2 percent and lower, is also
warranted when discounting intergenerational impacts. The costs presented in this table are 2026 annual estimates. Net compliance costs are the compliance costs minus the value of product recovery
from compliance with the rule. Hence, net compliance costs are negative if the value of product recovery exceeds the compliance costs. Rows may not appear to add correctly due to rounding.

6-3


-------
Table 6-3: Summary of Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits, Compliance Costs, and Net Benefits PV/EAV for
NSPS XXa, 2026-2040 (million 2019$, discounted to 2022)	

Proposal	Less Stringent Alternative	More Stringent Alternative

3%

PV

EAV

PV

EAV

PV

EAV

Health Benefits

$29(ST)
and

$2.4 (ST)
and

$2.4 (ST)
and

$0.20 (ST)
and

$29 (ST)
and

$2.4 (ST)
and



$240 (LT)

$20 (LT)

$20 (LT)

$1.6 (LT)

$240 (LT)

$20 (LT)

Climate Disbenefits(3%)

$4.4

$0.37

$4.4

$0.37

$4.4

$0.37

Net Compliance Costs

$9.0

$0.70

$3.0

$0.26

$10.0

$0.8

Compliance Costs

$41

$3.4

$5.7

$0.48

$42

$3.5

Value of Product Recovery

$32

$2.7

$2.7

$0.22

$32

$2.7

Net Benefits

$16(ST)
and

$1.3 (ST)
and

($5.0) (ST)
and

($0.43) (ST)
and

$15 (ST)
and

$1.2 (ST)
and



$230 (LT)

$19 (LT)

$13 (LT)

($0.97) (LT)

$230 (LT)

$19 (LT)

7%

Health Benefits

$16 (ST)
and

$1.7 (ST)
and

$1.3 (ST)
and

$0.15 (ST)
and

$16 (ST)
and

$1.8 (ST)
and



$130 (LT)

$15 (LT)

$11 (LT)

$1.2 (LT)

$130 (LT)

$15 (LT)

Climate Disbenefits (3%)

$4.4

$0.37

$4.4

$0.37

$4.4

$0.37

Net Compliance Costs

$5.0

$0.6

$1.9

$0.21

$6.0

$0.60

Compliance Costs

$26

$2.9

$3.6

$0.40

$27

$2.9

Value of Product Recovery

$21

$2.3

$1.7

$0.19

$21

$2.3

Net Benefits

$6.6 (ST)
and

$0.73 (ST)
and

($5.0) (ST)
and

($0.43) (ST)
and

$5.6 (ST)
and

$0.83 (ST)
and



$120 (LT)

$14 (LT)

$4.7 (LT)

$0.62 (LT)

$120 (LT)

$14 (LT)

Note: Monetized benefits include ozone related health benefits associated with reductions in VOC emissions. The health benefits are associated with several point estimates and are presented at real
discount rates of 3 and 7 percent for both short- (ST) and long-term (LT) benefits. The two benefits estimates are separated by the word "and" to signify that they are two separate estimates. The
estimates do not represent lower- and upper-bound estimates. Benefits from HAP reductions and VOC reductions outside of the ozone season remain unmonetized and are thus not reflected in the table.
The unmonetized effects also include disbenefits resulting from a secondary increase in N02, S02, and CO emissions. Please see Section 4.6 for more discussion of the climate disbenefits. Benefits
(incorporating disbenefits) include those related to public health and climate. The health benefits are associated with several point estimates and are presented at real discount rates of 3 and 7 percent.
Climate disbenefits are based on changes (increases) in C02 emissions and are calculated using four different estimates of the social cost of carbon (SC-C02) (model average at 2.5 percent, 3 percent,
and 5 percent discount rates; 95 th percentile at 3 percent discount rate). For the presentational purposes of this table, we show the disbenefits associated with the average SC-C02 at a 3 percent discount
rate, but the Agency does not have a single central SC-C02 point estimate. We emphasize the importance and value of considering the disbenefits calculated using all four SC-C02 estimates; please see
Table 4-8 for the full range of SC-C02 estimates. As discussed in Chapter 4, a consideration of climate disbenefits calculated using discount rates below 3 percent, including 2 percent and lower, is also
warranted when discounting intergenerational impacts. The costs presented in this table are 2026 annual estimates. Net compliance costs are the compliance costs minus the value of product recovery
from compliance with the rule. Hence, net compliance costs are negative if the value of product recovery exceeds the compliance costs. Rows may not appear to add correctly due to rounding.

6-4


-------
Table 6-4: Summary of Short-term and Long-term Monetized Benefits, Compliance Costs, and Net Benefits PV/EAV for All
Rules, 2026-2040 (million 2019$, discounted to 2022)	

Proposal	Less Stringent Alternative	More Stringent Alternative

3%

PV

EAV

PV

EAV

PV

EAV

Health Benefits
Climate Disbenefits(3%)

$220(ST)

and
$1,800 (LT)
$31

$18(ST)

and
$150 (LT)
$2.6

$56 (ST)

and
$460 (LT)
$31

$4.8 (ST)

and
$39 (LT)
$2.6

$270(ST)

and
$2,200 (LT)
$31

$22(ST)

and
$190 (LT)
$2.6

Net Compliance Costs

($39)

($2.4)

($1.7)

($0.07)

$363

$31

Compliance Costs

$211

$18

$59

$5.0

$656

$56

Value of Product Recovery

$250

$20

$61

$5.1

$293

$25

Net Benefits

$230(ST)
and
$1,800 (LT)

$18(ST)

and
$150 (LT)

$27 (ST)

and
$430 (LT)

$2.3 (ST)

and
$36 (LT)

($120) (ST)

and
$1,800 (LT)

($12) (ST)

and
$160 (LT)

7%

Health Benefits
Climate Disbenefits (3%)

$130 (ST)

and
$1,000 (LT)
$31

$14 (ST)

and
$120 (LT)
$2.6

$35(ST)

and
$280 (LT)
$31

$3.8 (ST)

and
$30 (LT)
$2.6

$160 (ST)

and
$1,300 (LT)
$31

$18 (ST)

and
$140 (LT)
$2.6

Net Compliance Costs

($22)

($2.7)

($0.9)

($0.1)

$250

$27

Compliance Costs

$140

$16

$40

$4.5

$444

$49

Value of Product Recovery

$170

$19

$41

$4.6

$201

$22

Net Benefits

$120 (ST)

and
$990 (LT)

$14 (ST)

and
$120 (LT)

$4.9 (ST)

and
$250 (LT)

$1.3 (ST)

and
$28 (LT)

($120) (ST)

and
$1,020 (LT)

($12) (ST)

and
$110 (LT)

Note: Monetized benefits include ozone related health benefits associated with reductions in VOC emissions. The health benefits are associated with several point estimates and are presented at real
discount rates of 3 and 7 percent for both short- (ST) and long-term (LT) benefits. The two benefits estimates are separated by the word "and" to signify that they are two separate estimates. The
estimates do not represent lower- and upper-bound estimates. Benefits from HAP reductions and VOC reductions outside of the ozone season remain unmonetized and are thus not reflected in the table.
The unmonetized effects also include disbenefits resulting from a secondary increase in N02, S02, and CO emissions. Please see Section 4.6 for more discussion of the climate disbenefits. Benefits
(incorporating disbenefits) include those related to public health and climate. The health benefits are associated with several point estimates and are presented at real discount rates of 3 and 7 percent.
Climate disbenefits are based on changes (increases) in C02 emissions and are calculated using four different estimates of the social cost of carbon (SC-C02) (model average at 2.5 percent, 3 percent,
and 5 percent discount rates; 95 th percentile at 3 percent discount rate). For the presentational purposes of this table, we show the disbenefits associated with the average SC-C02 at a 3 percent discount
rate, but the Agency does not have a single central SC-C02 point estimate. We emphasize the importance and value of considering the disbenefits calculated using all four SC-C02 estimates; please see
Table 4-8 for the full range of SC-C02 estimates. As discussed in Chapter 4, a consideration of climate disbenefits calculated using discount rates below 3 percent, including 2 percent and lower, is also
warranted when discounting intergenerational impacts. The costs presented in this table are 2026 annual estimates. Net compliance costs are the compliance costs minus the value of product recovery
from compliance with the rule. Hence, net compliance costs are negative if the value of product recovery exceeds the compliance costs. Rows may not appear to add correctly due to rounding.

6-5


-------
Given these results, the EPA expects that implementation of the GACT 6B, based solely
on an economic efficiency criterion, will provide society with a relatively substantial net gain in
welfare, notwithstanding the expansive set of health and environmental benefits and other
impacts we were unable to quantify such as monetization of benefits from VOC emission
reductions occurring outside of the ozone season (the months of October-April). The same holds
true for NSPS XXa and for all proposed amendments considered cumulatively. For the proposed
amendments to MACT R, net benefits are negative when considering only short-term benefits
but become positive when long-term benefits of reduced exposure to ozone are taken into
account. Further quantification of directly emitted VOC and HAP would increase the estimated
net benefits of the proposed action.

6.2 Uncertainties and Limitations

Throughout the RIA, we considered a number of sources of uncertainty, both
quantitatively and qualitatively, regarding the benefits, and costs of the proposed amendments.
We summarize the key elements of our discussions of uncertainty here:

• Projection methods and assumptions: Over time, more facilities are newly
established or modified in each year, and to the extent the facilities remain in
operation in future years, the total number of facilities subject to the action could
change. Facility closure affects the number of facilities subject to GACT 6B and
MACT R. We assume 100 percent compliance with these proposed rules and existing
rules, starting from when the source becomes affected. If sources do not comply with
these rules, at all or as written, the cost impacts and emission reductions may be
overestimated. Additionally, new control technology may become available in the
future at lower cost, and we are unable to predict exactly how industry will comply
with the proposed rules in the future.

In addition, the counts of units projected to be affected by this proposed action are
held constant. Given our analytical timeframe of 2026-2040, it is possible that the
affected unit counts may change. One factor that may impact these counts, and the
impacts of these proposed rules overall, is a potential increase in electric vehicle use
that could serve as a substitute for gasoline vehicles. AEO 2021 projections indicate

6-6


-------
a continued increase in battery electric and electric-hybrid vehicle use up to 2040.70
The expected consumption of gasoline as projected for this RIA may be senstitive to
such vehicle projections.

•	Years of analysis: The years of the cost analysis are 2026, to represent the first-year
facilities are fully compliant with MACT R and GACT 6B, through 2040, to
represent impacts of the action over the life of installed capital equipment, as
discussed in Chapter 3. Extending the analysis beyond 2040 would introduce
substantial and increasing uncertainties in projected impacts of the proposed
regulations.

•	Compliance Costs: There may be an opportunity cost associated with the installation
of environmental controls (for purposes of mitigating the emission of pollutants) that
is not reflected in the compliance costs included in Chapter 3. If environmental
investment displaces investment in productive capital, the difference between the rate
of return on the marginal investment (which is discretionary in nature) displaced by
the mandatory environmental investment is a measure of the opportunity cost of the
environmental requirement to the regulated entity. To the extent that any opportunity
costs are not included in the control costs, the compliance costs presented above for
this proposed action may be underestimated.

•	BPT estimates: All national-average BPT estimates reflect the geographic
distribution of the modeled emissions, which may not exactly match the emission
reductions that would occur due to the action, and they may not reflect local
variability in population density, meteorology, exposure, baseline health incidence
rates, or other local factors for any specific location. Recently, the EPA
systematically compared the changes in benefits, and concentrations where available,
from its BPT technique and other reduced-form techniques to the changes in benefits
and concentrations derived from full-form photochemical model representation of a
few different specific emissions scenarios. Reduced form tools are less complex than
the full air quality modeling, requiring less agency resources and time. That work, in

70 U.S. Energy Information Administration. Annual Energy Outlook 2021 Narrative. February 2021, p. 24.

Available at https://www.eia.gov/outlooks/aeo/pdf/AEO_Narrative_2021 .pdf.

6-7


-------
which we also explore other reduced form models is referred to as the "Reduced
Form Tool Evaluation Project" (Project), began in 2017, and the initial results were
available at the end of 2018. The Agency's goal was to better understand the
suitability of alternative reduced-form air quality modeling techniques for estimating
the health impacts of criteria pollutant emissions changes in the EPA's benefit-cost
analysis. The EPA continues to work to develop refined reduced-form approaches for
estimating benefits. The scenario-specific emission inputs developed for this project
are currently available online. The study design and methodology are described in the
final report summarizing the results of the project, available at
.

•	Non-monetized benefits: Numerous categories of health and welfare benefits are not
quantified and monetized in this RIA. These unquantified benefits, including benefits
from reductions in emissions of pollutants such as HAP which are to be reduced by
this proposed action, are described in detail in Chapter 4 of this RIA and various
NAAQS RIAs.

•	VOC health impacts: In this RIA, we quantify an array of adverse health impacts
attributable to emissions of VOC. The Integrated Science Assessment for Particulate
Matter (" ISA") (U.S. EPA, 2019) identifies the human health effects associated with
ambient particles, which include premature death and a variety of illnesses associated
with acute and chronic exposures.

•	Monetized climate disbenefits: The EPA considered the uncertainty associated with
the interim global social cost of carbon (SC-CO2) estimates, which were used to
calculate the climate disbenefits from the increase in CO2 emissions projected under
the proposed amendments to NSPS XX and GACT 6B. Some uncertainties are
captured within the analysis, while other areas of uncertainty have not yet been
quantified in a way that can be modeled.71 A full list and discussion of uncertainties

For more information on the uncertainty associated with SC-CO2 please see the RIA associated with the final ACE
rule. Section 4.3 and Chapter 7 of the ACE RIA provides a detailed discussion of the ways in which the modeling

6-8


-------
in the analysis of monetized climate disbenefits can be found in section 4 of this RIA.

underlying the development of the SC-CO2 estimates used in this analysis addresses quantified sources of
uncertainty and presents a sensitivity analysis to show consideration of the uncertainty surrounding discount rates
over long time horizons.

6-9


-------
7 REFERENCES

Agency for Toxic Substances and Disease Registry (ATSDR). 1997. Toxicological
Profile for Hexane. Draft for Public Comment. Public Health Service, U.S.
Department of Health and Human Services, Atlanta, GA.

Agency for Toxic Substances and Disease Registry (ATSDR). 2000. Toxicological
Profile for Toluene. U.S. Public Health Service, U.S. Department of Health and
Human Services, Atlanta, GA.

Agency for Toxic Substances and Disease Registry (ATSDR). 2005. Toxicological
Profile for Naphthalene, 1-Methylnapthalene, and 2- Methylnapthalene. Public Health
Service, U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, Atlanta, GA.

Agency for Toxic Substances and Disease Registry (ATSDR). 2007. Toxicological
Profile for Benzene. U.S. Public Health Service, U.S. Department of Health and
Human Services, Atlanta, GA.

Agency for Toxic Substances and Disease Registry (ATSDR). 2007. Toxicological
Profile for Xylene. Public Health Service, U.S. Department of Health and Human
Services, Altanta, GA.

Agency for Toxic Substances and Disease Registry (ATSDR). 2010. Toxicological
Profile for Ethylbenzene. Public Health Service, U.S. Department of Health and
Human Services, Atlanta, GA.

Arrow, K. J., Cropper, M. L., Eads, G. C., Hahn, R. J., Lave, L. B., Noll, R. J., . . .
Stavins, R. N. 1996. Benefit-Cost Analysis in Environmental, Health, and Saftey
Regulation: A Statement of Principles. American Enterprise Institute Press.

Bell, M.L., A. McDermott, S.L. Zeger, J.M. Sarnet, and F. Dominici. 2004. Ozone
and Short-Term Mortality in 95 U.S. Urban Communities, 1987-2000. Journal of the
American Medical Association. 292(19):2372-8.

Bell, M.L., F. Dominici, and J.M. Samet. 2005. A Meta-Analysis of Time-Series

7-1


-------
Studies of Ozone and Mortality with Comparison to the National Morbidity,
Mortality, and Air Pollution Study. Epidemiology. 16(4):436-45.

•	Bento, A. M., Goulder, L. H., Jacobsen, M. R., & von Haefen, R. H. 2009.
Distributional and Efficiency Impacts of Increased US Gasoline Taxes. American
Economic Review, 99(3), 667-699.

•	Blunden, J., and D.S. Arndt, Eds. 2020. State of the Climate in 2019. Bull. Amer.
Meteor. Soc, S1-S429, https://doi.Org/10.1175/2020BAMSStateoftheClimate.l.

•	Center for Climate and Security (CCS), The. 2018. Military Expert Panel Report Sea
Level Rise and the U.S. Military's Mission. Available at:
https://climateandsecurity.files.wordpress.com/2018/02/militaryexpert-panel-
report_sea-level-rise-and-the-us-militarys-mission_2nd-edition_02_2018.pdf
(accessed February 5, 2021).

•	Center for Sustainable Systems. 2021. Mobility Factsheets: Personal Transportation.
University of Michigan.

•	Chouinard, H., & Perloff, J. 2004. Incidence of federal and state gasoline taxes.
Economics Letters, 83, 55-60.

•	Coglianese, J., Davis, L. W., Kilian, L., & Stock, J. H. 2016. Anticipation, Tax
Avoidance, and the Price Elasticity of Gasoline. Journal of Applied Econometrics,
32(1), 1-15.

•	Considine, T. 2002. Inventories and Market Power in the World Crude Oil Market.
Working Paper.

•	Coyle, D., Debacker, J., & Prisinzano, R. 2012. Estimating the supply and demand of
gasoline using tax data. Energy Economics, 34(1), 195-200.

•	Desilver, D. (2021). Gasoline costs more these days, but price spikes have a long
history and happen for a lot of reasons. Pew Research Center.

7-2


-------
•	Hester, C., & Stephenson, T. 2006. Gasoline Distribution Area Source Baseline
Emission Estimates for 2004, sent to Stephen Shedd, U.S. Environmental Protection
Agency.

•	Huang Y, Dominici F, Bell M. 2004. Bayesian Hierarchical Distributed Lag Models
for Summer Ozone Exposure and Cardio-Respiratory Mortality. Johns Hopkins Univ
Dept Biostat Work Pap Ser.

•	Industrial Economics Inc. (IEc), for U.S. EPA/OAQPS. October 31, 2019.

Evaluating Reduced-Form Tools for Estimating Air Quality Benefits. Final Report.
Available at: .

•	Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). 2018. Global Warming of 1.5
°C. An IPCC Special Report on the impacts of global warming of 1.5 °C above pre-
industrial levels and related global greenhouse gas emission pathways, in the context
of strengthening the global response to the threat of climate change, sustainable
development, and efforts to eradicate poverty [Masson-Delmotte, V., P. Zhai, H.-O.
Po'rtner, D. Roberts, J. Skea, P.R. Shukla, A. Pirani, W. Moufouma-Okia, C. Pe'an,
R. Pidcock, S. Connors, J.B.R. Matthews, Y. Chen, X. Zhou, M.I. Gomis, E. Lonnoy,
T. Maycock, M. Tignor, and T. Waterfield (eds.)].

•	Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). 2019a. Climate Change and
Land: an IPCC special report on climate change, desertification, land degradation,
sustainable land management, food security, and greenhouse gas fluxes in terrestrial
ecosystems [P.R. Shukla, J. Skea, E. Calvo Buendia, V. Masson-Delmotte, H.-O.
Po' rtner, D.C. Roberts, P. Zhai, R. Slade, S. Connors, R. van Diemen, M. Ferrat, E.
Haughey, S. Luz, S. Neogi, M. Pathak, J. Petzold, J. Portugal Pereira, P. Vyas, E.
Huntley, K. Kissick, M. Belkacemi, J. Malley, (eds.)]

•	Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). 2019b. IPCC Special Report on
the Ocean and Cryosphere in a Changing Climate [H.-O. Po "rtner, D.C. Roberts, V.
Masson-Delmotte, P. Zhai M. Tignor, E. Poloczanska, K. Mintenbeck, A. Alegn'a,

7-3


-------
M. Nicolai, A. Okem, J. Petzold, B. Rama, N.M. Weyer (eds.)].

•	Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). 2021. Summary for
Policymakers. In: Climate Change 2021: The Physical Science Basis. Contribution of
Working Group I to the Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on
Climate Change [Masson-Delmotte, V., P. Zhai, A. Pirani, S.L. Connors, C. Pe'an, S.
Berger, N. Caud, Y. Chen, L. Goldfarb, M.I. Gomis, M. Huang, K. Leitzell, E.
Lonnoy, J.B.R. Matthews, T.K. Maycock, T. Waterfield, O. Yelekcj, R. Yu and B.
Zhou (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press. In Press.

•	Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). 2022a. Chapter 2: Terrestrial
and Freshwater Ecosystems and their Services. In: Climate Change 2022: Impacts,
Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Sixth
Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. [Parmesan,
Morecroft, Trisurat, et al.] Cambridge University Press. In Press.
https://report.ipcc.ch/ar6wg2/pdf/IPCC_AR6_WGII_FinalDraft_Chapter02.pdf

•	Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). 2022b. Chapter 14: North
America. In: Climate Change 2022: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability.
Contribution of Working Group II to the Sixth Assessment Report of the
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. [Hicke, Lucatello, Mortsch, et al.]
Cambridge University Press. In Press.

https://report.ipcc.ch/ar6wg2/pdf/IPCC_AR6_WGII_FinalDraft_Chapterl4.pdf

•	International Agency for Research on Cancer (IARC). 2000. Ethylbenzene.
Monographs on the evaluation of carcinogenic risk of chemicals to humans, Volume
77.

•	International Agency for Research on Cancer IARC. 2002. Some traditional herbal
medicines, some mycotoxins, naphthalene and styrene. IARC Monographs on the
Evaluation of Carcinogenic Risks to Humans, Volume 82.

•	International Agency for Research on Cancer IARC. 2013. Some Chemicals Present

7-4


-------
in Industrial and Consumer Products, Food, and Drinking-water. IARC Monographs
on the Evaluation of Carcinogenic Risks to Humans, Volume 101.

•	International Agency for Research on Cancer (IARC). 2018. Monographs on the
evaluation of carcinogenic risk of chemicals to humans, Volume 120, Benzene,

World Health Organization, Lyon, France.

•	Ito, K., S.F. De Leon, and M. Lippmann. 2005. Associations Between Ozone and
Daily Mortality: Analysis and Meta-Analysis. Epidemiology. 16(4):446-57.

•	Jerrett M, Burnett RT, Pope CA, Ito K, Thurston G, Krewski D, et al. 2009. Long-
term ozone exposure and mortality. N Engl J Med 360:1085-95;
doi:10.1056/NEJMoa0803894.

•	Jhun I, Fann N, Zanobetti A, Hubbell B. 2014. Effect modification of ozone-related
mortality risks by temperature in 97 US cities. Environment International. 73:128-34.

•	Katsouyanni, K, Samet, JM, Anderson, HR, Atkinson, R, Le Tertre, A, Medina, S,
Samoli, E, Touloumi, G, Burnett, RT, Krewski, D, Ramsay, T, Dominici, F, Peng,
RD, Schwartz, J, Zanobetti, A and Committee, HEIHR (2009). Air pollution and
health: a European and North American approach (APHENA/ Res Rep Health Eff
Inst( 142): 5-90.

•	Levin, L., Lewis, M. S., & Wolak, F. A. 2017. High Frequency Evidence on the
Demand for Gasoline. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 314-347.

•	Levy, J.I., S.M. Chemerynski, and J.A. Sarnat. 2005. Ozone Exposure and Mortality:
An Empiric Bayes Metaregression Analysis. Epidemiology. 16(4):458-68.

•	Moriarty, K. 2016. High Octane Fuel: Terminal Backgrounder. Golden, Colorado:
National Renewable Energy Laboratory.

•	National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and Medicine. 2016. Attribution of
Extreme Weather Events in the Context of Climate Change. Washington, DC: The
National Academies Press, https://dio.org/10.17226/21852.

7-5


-------
•	National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and Medicine (National Academies).
2017. Valuing Climate Damages: Updating Estimation of the Social Cost of Carbon
Dioxide. Washington, D.C.: National Academies Press.

https://doi.org/10.17226/24651.

•	National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and Medicine. 2019. Climate Change
and Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press.
https://doi.org/10.17226/25504.

•	National Toxicology Program. 1999. Toxicology and Carcinogenesis Studies of
Ethylbenzene (CAS No. 100-41-4) in F344/N Rats and B6C3F1 Mice (Inhalation
Studies). TRNo. 466. U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, Public Health
Service, National Institutes of Health, Bethesda, MD.

•	NRC (2002). Estimating the public health benefits of proposed air pollution
regulations. 0309086094. National Academies Press.

•	Office of Management and Budget. 2015. 2015 Report to Congress on the Benefits
and Costs of Federal Regulations and Agency Compliance with the Unfunded
Mandates Reform Act. U.S. Office of Management and Budget, Office of
Information and Regulatory Affairs.

•	Ren, C., G.M. Williams, K. Mengersen, L. Morawska, and S. Tong. 2008a. Does
Temperature Modify Short-Term Effects of Ozone on Total Mortality in 60 Large
Eastern U.S. Communities? An Assessment Using the NMMAPS Data. Environment
International. 34:451-458.

•	Ren, C., G.M. William, L. Morawska, K. Mengensen, and S. Tong. 2008b. Ozone
Modifies Associations between Temperature and Cardiovascular Mortality: Analysis
of the NMMAPS Data. Occupational and Environmental Medicine. 65:255-260.

•	RTI International, Coburn, J. 2021. Memorandum to Njeri Moeller and Jennifer
Caparoso, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. Control Options for Loading
Operations at Gasoline Distribution Facilities. EPA-HQ-OAR-2020-0371.

7-6


-------
•	RTI International, Coburn, J. 2021. Memorandum to Njeri Moeller and Jennifer
Caparoso. Control Options for Storage Tanks at Gasoline Distribution Facilities.
EP A-HQ-0 AR-2020-03 71.

•	RTI International, Coburn, J. 2022. Memorandum to Njeri Moeller and Jennifer
Caparoso, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. Monitoring Options and Costs for
Gasoline Distribution Facilitities. EPA-HQ-OAR-2020-0371.

•	RTI International, Delang, M., & Coburn, J. 2021. Memorandum to Njeri Moeller
and Jennifer Caparoso, Environmental Protection Agency. Control Options for
Equipment Leaks at Gasoline Distribution Facilities. EPA-HQ-OAR-2020-0371.

•	RTI International, Delang, M., & Coburn, J. 2021. Memorandum to Njeri Moeller
and Jennifer Caparoso, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. Area Source
Technology Review for the Gasoline Distribution Bulk Terminals, Bulk Plants, and
Pipeline Facilities NESHAP. EPA-HQ-OAR-2020-0371.

•	RTI International, Delang, M., & Coburn, J. 2021. Memorandum to Njeri Moeller
and Jennifer Caparoso, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. Major Source
Technology Review for Gasoline Distribution Facilities (Bulk Gasoline Terminals
and Pipeline Breakout Stations) NESHAP. EPA-HQ-OAR-2020-0371.

•	RTI International, Delang, M., & Coburn, J. 2021. Memorandum to Njeri Moeller
and Jennifer Caparoso, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. New Source
Performance Standards Review for Bulk Gasoline Terminals. EPA-HQ-OAR-2020-
0371.

•	Schwartz, J. 2005. How Sensitive is the Association between Ozone and Daily Deaths
to Control for Temperature? American Journal of Respiratory and Critical Care
Medicine. 171(6): 627-31.

•	Sittig, M. 1985. Handbook of Toxic and Hazardous Chemicals and Carcinogens. 2nd
ed. Noyes Publications, Park Ridge, NJ.

7-7


-------
Smith RL, Xu B, Switzer P. 2009. Reassessing the relationship between ozone and
short-term mortality in U.S. urban communities. Inhal Toxicol 21 Suppl 2:37-61;
doi: 10.1080/08958370903161612.

Turner, MC, Jerrett, M, Pope, A, III, Krewski, D, Gapstur, SM, Diver, WR,
Beckerman, BS, Marshall, JD, Su, J, Crouse, DL and Burnett, RT (2016). Long-term
ozone exposure and mortality in a large prospective study. Am JRespir Crit Care
Med 193(10): 1134-1142.

U.S. Department of Defense (DOD). 2014. Climate Change Adaptation Roadmap.
Available at: https://www.acq.osd.mil/eie/downloads/CCARprint_wForward_e.pdf
(accessed February 5, 2021).

U.S. Department of Defense (DOD), Office of the Undersecretary for Policy
(Strategy, Plans, and Capabilities). 2021. Department of Defense Climate Risk
Analysis. Report Submitted to National Security Council.

https://media.defense.gov/202 l/Oct/21/20028773 53/-1/-1/0/DOD-CLIMATE-RISK-
ANALYSIS-FINAL PDF.

U.S. Department of Health and Human Services. Hazardous Substances Data Bank
(HSDB, online database). 1993. National Toxicology Information Program, National
Library of Medicine, Bethesda, MD.

U.S. EPA. 1980. Bulk Gasoline Terminals - Background Information for Promulgated
Standards. EPA-450/3-80-038a.

U.S. EPA. 1980. Bulk Gasoline Terminals - Background Information for Proposed
Standards. EPA-450/3-80-038a.

U.S. EPA. 1988. Integrated Risk Information System (IRIS) on Ethylbenzene.
National Center for Environmental Assessment, Office of Research and
Development, Washington, DC.

U.S. EPA. 1994. Gasoline Distribution Industry (Stage 1) - Background Information

7-8


-------
for Promulgated Standards. EPA-453/R-94-002b.

•	U.S. EPA. 1994. Gasoline Distribution Industry (Stage 1) - Background Information
for Proposed Standards. EPA-453/R-94-002a.

•	U.S. EPA. 1997. Toxicological Review of Cumene (CAS No. 98-82-8). In Support of
Summary Information on the Integrated Risk Information System. National Center
for Environmental Assessment, Office of Research and Development, Washington,
DC.

•	U.S. EPA. 1998. Toxicological Review of Naphthalene (CAS No. 91-20-3) in
Support of Summary Information on the Integrated Risk Information System (IRIS).
National Center for Environmental Assessment, Cincinnati, OH.

•	U.S. EPA. 2000. Integrated Risk Information System (IRIS) on Benzene. National
Center for Environmental Assessment, Office of Research and Development,
Washington, DC.

•	U.S. EPA. 2003. Integrated Risk Information System (IRIS) on Xylenes. National
Center for Environmental Assessment, Office of Research and Development,
Washington, DC.

•	U.S. EPA. 2005a. Integrated Risk Information System (IRIS) on n-Hexane. National
Center for Environmental Assessment, Office of Research and Development,
Washington, DC.

•	U.S. EPA. 2005b. Integrated Risk Information System (IRIS) on Toluene. National
Center for Environmental Assessment, Office of Research and Development,
Washington, DC.

•	U.S. EPA. 2006. Gasoline Distribution Area Source Emission Reduction Estimates.

•	U.S. EPA. 2007. Integrated Risk Information System (IRIS) on 2,2,4-
Trimethylpentane. National Center for Environmental Assessment, Office of
Research and Development, Washington, DC.

7-9


-------
U.S. EPA. 2008. Economic Impact Analysis for the Gasoline Distribution Industry
(Area Sources). Research Triangle Institute for U.S. EPA, Final Report. Available at
https://www.epa.gov/sites/default/files/2020-07/documents/gasoline-
distributioneiafinalO 1 -2008.pdf.

U.S. EPA. 2009. Integrated Science Assessment for Particulate Matter (Final Report).
EPA-600-R-08-139F. National Center for Environmental Assessment—RTP
Division. Available at:

.

U.S. EPA. 2015. Regulatory Impact Analysis of the Final Revisions to the National
Ambient Air Quality Standards for Ground-Level Ozone. Office of Air Quality
Planning and Standards, Health and Environmental Impacts Division. Research
Triangle Park, NC. U.S. EPA. EPA-452/R-15-007. Available at:
.

U.S. EPA. 2016. Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses. Available at: <
https://www.epa.gov/environmental-economics/guidelines-preparing-economic-
analyse s>.

U.S. EPA. 2017a. EPA Air Pollution Control Cost Manual. Office of Air Quality
Planning and Standards. Available at: < https://www.epa.gov/economic-and-cost-
analysis-air-pollution-regulations/cost-reports-and-guidance-air-pollution>.

U.S. EPA. 2017b. SAB Review of EPA's Proposed Methodology for Updating
Mortality Risk Valuation Estimates for Policy Analysis.

U.S. EPA. 2019. Regulatory Impact Analysis for the Repeal of the Clean Power Plan,
and the Emissions Guidelines for Greenhouse Gases from Existing Electric Energy
Generating Units. EPA-452/R-19-003. Available at


U.S. EPA. 2020. Integrated Science Assessment for Ozone and Related

7-10


-------
Photochemical Oxidants. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. Washington, DC.
Office of Research and Development. EPA/600/R-20/012. Available at:
.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (U.S. EPA). 2021a. Climate Change and
Social Vulnerability in the United States: A Focus on Six Impacts. U.S.
Environmental Protection Agency, EPA 430-R-21-003.

U.S. EPA. 2021b. Estimating the Benefit per Ton of Reducing PM2.5 Precursors
from 21 Sectors. Technical Support Document. Available at:
.

U.S. EPA. 2021c. Regulatory Impact Analysis Final Revised Cross-State Air
Pollution Rule Update for the 2008 Ozone NAAQS. Available at


U.S. EPA. 2021d. Technical Support Document (TSD) for the Final Revised Cross-
State Air Pollution Rule Update for the 2008 Ozone Season NAAQS Estimating
PM2.5- and Ozone-Attributable Health Benefits. Available at


U.S. EPA-SAB. 2000. An SAB Report on EPA's White Paper Valuing the Benefits
of Fatal Cancer Risk Reduction.

U.S. EPA-SAB. 2010. Review of EPA's Draft Health Benefits of the Second Section
812 Prospective Study of the CAA.

U.S. Global Change Research Program (USGCRP). 2016. The Impacts of Climate
Change on Human Health in the United States: A Scientific Assessment. Crimmins,
A., J. Balbus, J.L. Gamble, C.B. Beard, J.E. Bell, D. Dodgen, R.J. Eisen, N. Fann,
M.D. Hawkins, S.C. Herring, L. Jantarasami, D.M. Mills, S. Saha, M.C. Sarofim, J.

7-11


-------
Trtanj, and L. Ziska, Eds. U.S. Global Change Research Program, Washington, DC,
312 pp. doi:.

•	U.S. Global Change Research Program (USGCRP). 2017. Climate Science Special
Report: Fourth National Climate Assessment, Volume I [Wuebbles, D.J., D.W.
Fahey, K.A. Hibbard, D.J. Dokken, B.C. Stewart, and T.K. Maycock (eds.)]. U.S.
Global Change Research Program, Washington, DC, USA, 470 pp, doi:
10.7930/J0J964J6.

•	U.S. Global Change Research Program (USGCRP). 2018. Impacts, Risks, and
Adaptation in the United States: Fourth National Climate Assessment, Volume II
[Reidmiller, D.R., C.W. Avery, D.R. Easterling, K.E. Kunkel, K.L.M. Lewis, T.K.
Maycock, and B.C. Stewart (eds.)]. U.S. Global Change Research Program,
Washington, DC, USA, 1515 pp. doi: 10.7930/NCA4.2018

•	Zanobetti A, Schwartz J. 2008. Mortality displacement in the association of ozone
with mortality: an analysis of 48 cities in the United States. Am JRespir Crit Care
Med 177:184-9; doi: 10.1164/rccm.200706-8230C.

7-12


-------
8 APPENDIX A: DETAILED MARKET IMPACT TABLES
8.1 Proposed Options
8.1.1 Price Impacts

Table 8-1: Projected Change in Price, Proposed Options (2019 cents/gallon of gasoline)

Year

NSPS XXa

MACTR

GACT 6B

All

2026

0.0005

0.0012

0.0048

0.0065

2027

0.0007

0.0012

0.0049

0.0067

2028

0.0008

0.0012

0.0049

0.0069

2029

0.0010

0.0012

0.0049

0.0071

2030

0.0011

0.0012

0.0050

0.0073

2031

0.0012

0.0012

0.0050

0.0074

2032

0.0014

0.0012

0.0050

0.0076

2033

0.0015

0.0012

0.0050

0.0078

2034

0.0017

0.0012

0.0051

0.0079

2035

0.0018

0.0012

0.0051

0.0081

2036

0.0020

0.0012

0.0051

0.0082

2037

0.0021

0.0012

0.0051

0.0084

2038

0.0022

0.0012

0.0051

0.0086

2039

0.0024

0.0012

0.0051

0.0087

2040

0.0025

0.0012

0.0051

0.0088

Table 8-2: Projected Percentage Change in Price, Proposed Options

Year

NSPS XXa

MACTR

GACT 6B

All

2026

0.0002%

0.0005%

0.0019%

0.0026%

2027

0.0003%

0.0005%

0.0019%

0.0027%

2028

0.0003%

0.0005%

0.0019%

0.0027%

2029

0.0004%

0.0004%

0.0019%

0.0027%

2030

0.0004%

0.0004%

0.0018%

0.0026%

2031

0.0004%

0.0004%

0.0018%

0.0027%

2032

0.0005%

0.0004%

0.0018%

0.0027%

2033

0.0005%

0.0004%

0.0018%

0.0027%

2034

0.0006%

0.0004%

0.0017%

0.0027%

2035

0.0006%

0.0004%

0.0017%

0.0028%

2036

0.0007%

0.0004%

0.0017%

0.0028%

2037

0.0007%

0.0004%

0.0017%

0.0028%

2038

0.0007%

0.0004%

0.0017%

0.0028%

2039

0.0008%

0.0004%

0.0017%

0.0029%

2040

0.0008%

0.0004%

0.0017%

0.0029%

8-1


-------
8,1,2 Quantity Impacts

Table 8-3: Projected Change in Quantity, Proposed Options (gallons of gasoline)

Year

NSPS XXa

MACTR

GACT 6B

All

2026

-86,000

-190,000

-790,000

-1,100,000

2027

-110,000

-190,000

-780,000

-1,100,000

2028

-120,000

-180,000

-760,000

-1,100,000

2029

-140,000

-180,000

-750,000

-1,100,000

2030

-160,000

-170,000

-710,000

-1,000,000

2031

-170,000

-170,000

-710,000

-1,100,000

2032

-190,000

-170,000

-690,000

-1,100,000

2033

-210,000

-170,000

-690,000

-1,100,000

2034

-220,000

-160,000

-680,000

-1,100,000

2035

-240,000

-160,000

-680,000

-1,100,000

2036

-260,000

-160,000

-670,000

-1,100,000

2037

-270,000

-160,000

-660,000

-1,100,000

2038

-290,000

-160,000

-650,000

-1,100,000

2039

-300,000

-160,000

-650,000

-1,100,000

2040

-320,000

-150,000

-640,000

-1,100,000

Table 8-4: Percentage Change in

Quantity, Proposed Options



Year

NSPS XXa

MACTR

GACT 6B

All

2026

-0.0001%

-0.0001%

-0.0006%

-0.0008%

2027

-0.0001%

-0.0001%

-0.0006%

-0.0008%

2028

-0.0001%

-0.0001%

-0.0006%

-0.0008%

2029

-0.0001%

-0.0001%

-0.0006%

-0.0008%

2030

-0.0001%

-0.0001%

-0.0006%

-0.0008%

2031

-0.0001%

-0.0001%

-0.0006%

-0.0008%

2032

-0.0002%

-0.0001%

-0.0006%

-0.0008%

2033

-0.0002%

-0.0001%

-0.0005%

-0.0008%

2034

-0.0002%

-0.0001%

-0.0005%

-0.0009%

2035

-0.0002%

-0.0001%

-0.0005%

-0.0009%

2036

-0.0002%

-0.0001%

-0.0005%

-0.0009%

2037

-0.0002%

-0.0001%

-0.0005%

-0.0009%

2038

-0.0002%

-0.0001%

-0.0005%

-0.0009%

2039

-0.0002%

-0.0001%

-0.0005%

-0.0009%

2040

-0.0003%

-0.0001%

-0.0005%

-0.0009%

8-2


-------
8.2 Less Stringent Alternative Options

8,2,1 Price Impacts

Table 8-5: Projected Change in Price, Less Stringent Alternative Options (2019
cents/gallon of gasoline)	

Year

NSPS XXa

MACTR

GACT 6B

All

2026

0.0001

0.0009

0.0010

0.0019

2027

0.0001

0.0009

0.0010

0.0019

2028

0.0001

0.0009

0.0010

0.0020

2029

0.0001

0.0009

0.0010

0.0020

2030

0.0002

0.0009

0.0010

0.0020

2031

0.0002

0.0009

0.0010

0.0021

2032

0.0002

0.0009

0.0010

0.0021

2033

0.0002

0.0009

0.0010

0.0021

2034

0.0002

0.0009

0.0010

0.0022

2035

0.0003

0.0009

0.0010

0.0022

2036

0.0003

0.0009

0.0010

0.0022

2037

0.0003

0.0009

0.0010

0.0022

2038

0.0003

0.0009

0.0010

0.0022

2039

0.0003

0.0009

0.0010

0.0023

2040

0.0004

0.0009

0.0010

0.0023

Table 8-6: Projected Percentage Change in Price, Less Stringent Alternative Options

Year

NSPS XXa

MACTR

GACT 6B

All

2026

0.0000%

0.0003%

0.0004%

0.0008%

2027

0.0000%

0.0003%

0.0004%

0.0008%

2028

0.0000%

0.0003%

0.0004%

0.0008%

2029

0.0000%

0.0003%

0.0004%

0.0008%

2030

0.0001%

0.0003%

0.0004%

0.0007%

2031

0.0001%

0.0003%

0.0004%

0.0007%

2032

0.0001%

0.0003%

0.0004%

0.0007%

2033

0.0001%

0.0003%

0.0004%

0.0007%

2034

0.0001%

0.0003%

0.0004%

0.0007%

2035

0.0001%

0.0003%

0.0004%

0.0007%

2036

0.0001%

0.0003%

0.0004%

0.0007%

2037

0.0001%

0.0003%

0.0004%

0.0007%

2038

0.0001%

0.0003%

0.0003%

0.0007%

2039

0.0001%

0.0003%

0.0003%

0.0008%

2040

0.0001%

0.0003%

0.0003%

0.0007%

8-3


-------
8,2,2 Quantity Impacts

Table 8-7: Projected Change in Quantity, Less Stringent Alternative Options (gallons of
gasoline)	

Year

NSPS XXa

MACTR

GACT 6B

All

2026

-12,000

-140,000

-160,000

-310,000

2027

-15,000

-140,000

-160,000

-310,000

2028

-17,000

-130,000

-160,000

-310,000

2029

-20,000

-130,000

-150,000

-300,000

2030

-22,000

-120,000

-150,000

-290,000

2031

-24,000

-120,000

-150,000

-290,000

2032

-26,000

-120,000

-140,000

-290,000

2033

-29,000

-120,000

-140,000

-290,000

2034

-31,000

-120,000

-140,000

-290,000

2035

-33,000

-120,000

-140,000

-290,000

2036

-35,000

-120,000

-140,000

-290,000

2037

-38,000

-120,000

-140,000

-290,000

2038

-40,000

-110,000

-130,000

-290,000

2039

-42,000

-110,000

-130,000

-290,000

2040

-44,000

-110,000

-130,000

-290,000

Table 8-8: Percentage Change in

Quantity, Less Stringent Alternative Options



Year

NSPS XXa

MACTR

GACT 6B

All

2026

0.0000%

-0.0001%

-0.0001%

-0.0002%

2027

0.0000%

-0.0001%

-0.0001%

-0.0002%

2028

0.0000%

-0.0001%

-0.0001%

-0.0002%

2029

0.0000%

-0.0001%

-0.0001%

-0.0002%

2030

0.0000%

-0.0001%

-0.0001%

-0.0002%

2031

0.0000%

-0.0001%

-0.0001%

-0.0002%

2032

0.0000%

-0.0001%

-0.0001%

-0.0002%

2033

0.0000%

-0.0001%

-0.0001%

-0.0002%

2034

0.0000%

-0.0001%

-0.0001%

-0.0002%

2035

0.0000%

-0.0001%

-0.0001%

-0.0002%

2036

0.0000%

-0.0001%

-0.0001%

-0.0002%

2037

0.0000%

-0.0001%

-0.0001%

-0.0002%

2038

0.0000%

-0.0001%

-0.0001%

-0.0002%

2039

0.0000%

-0.0001%

-0.0001%

-0.0002%

2040

0.0000%

-0.0001%

-0.0001%

-0.0002%

8-4


-------
8.3 More Stringent Alternative Options

8,3,1 Price Impacts

Table 8-9: Projected Change in Price, More Stringent Alternative Options (2019
cents/gallon of gasoline)	

Year

NSPS XXa

MACTR

GACT 6B

All

2026

0.0005

0.0030

0.0180

0.0220

2027

0.0007

0.0030

0.0180

0.0220

2028

0.0008

0.0030

0.0180

0.0220

2029

0.0010

0.0030

0.0180

0.0230

2030

0.0011

0.0031

0.0190

0.0230

2031

0.0013

0.0031

0.0190

0.0230

2032

0.0014

0.0031

0.0190

0.0230

2033

0.0015

0.0031

0.0190

0.0240

2034

0.0017

0.0031

0.0190

0.0240

2035

0.0018

0.0031

0.0190

0.0240

2036

0.0020

0.0031

0.0190

0.0240

2037

0.0021

0.0031

0.0190

0.0240

2038

0.0023

0.0031

0.0190

0.0250

2039

0.0024

0.0031

0.0190

0.0250

2040

0.0026

0.0031

0.0190

0.0250

Table 8-10: Projected Percentage Change in Price, More Stringent Alternative Options

Year

NSPS XXa

MACTR

GACT 6B

All

2026

0.0002%

0.0012%

0.0072%

0.0087%

2027

0.0003%

0.0012%

0.0072%

0.0087%

2028

0.0003%

0.0012%

0.0071%

0.0086%

2029

0.0004%

0.0012%

0.0070%

0.0085%

2030

0.0004%

0.0011%

0.0067%

0.0082%

2031

0.0005%

0.0011%

0.0067%

0.0083%

2032

0.0005%

0.0011%

0.0066%

0.0082%

2033

0.0005%

0.0011%

0.0066%

0.0083%

2034

0.0006%

0.0011%

0.0066%

0.0082%

2035

0.0006%

0.0011%

0.0065%

0.0082%

2036

0.0007%

0.0011%

0.0065%

0.0082%

2037

0.0007%

0.0011%

0.0064%

0.0082%

2038

0.0008%

0.0010%

0.0063%

0.0081%

2039

0.0008%

0.0010%

0.0063%

0.0082%

2040

0.0008%

0.0010%

0.0062%

0.0081%

8-5


-------
8,3,2 Quantity Impacts

Table 8-11: Projected Change in Quantity, More Stringent Alternative Options (gallons of
gasoline)	

Year

NSPS XXa

MACTR

GACT 6B

All

2026

-88,000

-480,000

-2,900,000

-3,500,000

2027

-110,000

-480,000

-2,900,000

-3,500,000

2028

-130,000

-470,000

-2,800,000

-3,400,000

2029

-150,000

-460,000

-2,800,000

-3,400,000

2030

-160,000

-440,000

-2,700,000

-3,300,000

2031

-180,000

-440,000

-2,700,000

-3,300,000

2032

-190,000

-430,000

-2,600,000

-3,200,000

2033

-210,000

-420,000

-2,600,000

-3,200,000

2034

-230,000

-420,000

-2,500,000

-3,200,000

2035

-240,000

-420,000

-2,500,000

-3,200,000

2036

-260,000

-410,000

-2,500,000

-3,200,000

2037

-280,000

-410,000

-2,500,000

-3,200,000

2038

-290,000

-400,000

-2,400,000

-3,100,000

2039

-310,000

-400,000

-2,400,000

-3,100,000

2040

-320,000

-390,000

-2,400,000

-3,100,000

Table 8-12: Percentage Change in

Quantity, More Stringent Alternative Options

Year

NSPS XXa

MACTR

GACT 6B

All

2026

-0.0001%

-0.0004%

-0.0022%

-0.0027%

2027

-0.0001%

-0.0004%

-0.0022%

-0.0027%

2028

-0.0001%

-0.0004%

-0.0022%

-0.0027%

2029

-0.0001%

-0.0004%

-0.0022%

-0.0026%

2030

-0.0001%

-0.0003%

-0.0021%

-0.0026%

2031

-0.0001%

-0.0003%

-0.0021%

-0.0026%

2032

-0.0002%

-0.0003%

-0.0021%

-0.0026%

2033

-0.0002%

-0.0003%

-0.0021%

-0.0026%

2034

-0.0002%

-0.0003%

-0.0020%

-0.0025%

2035

-0.0002%

-0.0003%

-0.0020%

-0.0025%

2036

-0.0002%

-0.0003%

-0.0020%

-0.0025%

2037

-0.0002%

-0.0003%

-0.0020%

-0.0025%

2038

-0.0002%

-0.0003%

-0.0020%

-0.0025%

2039

-0.0002%

-0.0003%

-0.0020%

-0.0025%

2040

-0.0003%

-0.0003%

-0.0019%

-0.0025%

8-6


-------
9 APPENDIX B: DISCOUNTED COST FOR THE PROPOSED OPTIONS TABLES BY RULE
9.1 NSPS XXa

Table 9-1: Discounted Capital and O&M Costs, Proposed Options, for NSPS XXa, 2026-2040 (million $2019)

3 percent











Total







Total

Year

Capital Cost

Operating and
Maintenance
Cost

Revenue from
Product
Recovery

Annualized
Cost with
Revenue from
Product
Recovery

Capital Cost

Operating and
Maintenance
Cost

Revenue from
Product
Recovery

Annualized
Cost with
Revenue from
Product
Recovery

2026

$0.34

$0.84

$1.00

$0.18

$0.29

$0.72

$0.86

$0.15

2027

$0.42

$1.00

$1.2

$0.22

$0.34

$0.84

$1.00

$0.18

2028

$0.49

$1.2

$1.4

$0.25

$0.39

$0.95

$1.10

$0.20

2029

$0.55

$1.3

$1.6

$0.29

$0.42

$1.00

$1.2

$0.22

2030

$0.61

$1.5

$1.8

$0.32

$0.45

$1.1

$1.3

$0.24

2031

$0.67

$1.6

$1.9

$0.35

$0.47

$1.2

$1.4

$0.25

2032

$0.72

$1.8

$2.1

$0.38

$0.49

$1.2

$1.4

$0.26

2033

$0.77

$1.9

$2.2

$0.40

$0.50

$1.2

$1.5

$0.26

2034

$0.81

$2.0

$2.4

$0.43

$0.51

$1.3

$1.5

$0.27

2035

$0.85

$2.1

$2.5

$0.45

$0.52

$1.3

$1.5

$0.27

2036

$0.89

$2.2

$2.6

$0.47

$0.52

$1.3

$1.5

$0.27

2037

$0.93

$2.3

$2.7

$0.49

$0.52

$1.3

$1.5

$0.27

2038

$0.96

$2.4

$2.8

$0.50

$0.52

$1.3

$1.5

$0.27

2039

$0.99

$2.4

$2.9

$0.52

$0.52

$1.3

$1.5

$0.27

2040

$1.0

$2.5

$3.0

$0.53

$0.51

$1.3

$1.5

$0.27

Note: Discounted to 2022

9-1


-------
Table 9-2: Discounted Costs, Proposed Options, for NSPS XXa, 2026-2040 (million $2019)

3 percent

7 percent

Annualized Costs (w/o
ear Revenue)

Revenue from Product
Recovery

Annualized Costs
(with Revenue)

Annualized Costs (w/o
Revenue)

Revenue from Product
Recovery

Annualized Costs
(with Revenue)

2026

$1.3

$1.00

$0.27

$1.10

$0.86

$0.24

2027

$1.6

$1.2

$0.33

$1.3

$1.00

$0.28

2028

$1.8

$1.4

$0.39

$1.4

$1.10

$0.31

2029

$2.0

$1.6

$0.44

$1.6

$1.2

$0.34

2030

$2.3

$1.8

$0.49

$1.7

$1.3

$0.36

2031

$2.5

$1.9

$0.53

$1.8

$1.4

$0.38

2032

$2.7

$2.1

$0.58

$1.8

$1.4

$0.39

2033

$2.9

$2.2

$0.61

$1.9

$1.5

$0.40

2034

$3.0

$2.4

$0.65

$1.9

$1.5

$0.41

2035

$3.2

$2.5

$0.68

$1.9

$1.5

$0.42

2036

$3.3

$2.6

$0.72

$2.0

$1.5

$0.42

2037

$3.5

$2.7

$0.74

$2.0

$1.5

$0.42

2038

$3.6

$2.8

$0.77

$2.0

$1.5

$0.42

2039

$3.7

$2.9

$0.80

$1.9

$1.5

$0.42

2040

$3.8

$3.0

$0.82

$1.9

$1.5

$0.41

Note: Discounted to 2022

9-2


-------
9.2 MACT R

Table 9-3: Discounted Capital and O&M Costs, Proposed Options, for MAC ! R, 2026-2040 ($2019)

3 percent



Year

Capital Cost

Operating and
Maintenance
Cost

Revenue
from Product
Recovery

Total Annualized
Cost with
Revenue from
Product Recovery

Capital Cost

Operating and
Maintenance
Cost

Revenue from
Product
Recovery

Total Annualized
Cost with
Revenue from
Product Recovery

2026

$0.15

$2.6

$0.92

$1.8

$0.13

$2.2

$0.79

$1.6

2027

$0.14

$2.5

$0.90

$1.8

$0.12

$2.1

$0.74

$1.5

2028

$0.14

$2.4

$0.87

$1.7

$0.11

$1.9

$0.69

$1.4

2029

$0.14

$2.4

$0.84

$1.7

$0.10

$1.8

$0.65

$1.3

2030

$0.13

$2.3

$0.82

$1.6

$0.10

$1.7

$0.60

$1.2

2031

$0.13

$2.2

$0.80

$1.6

$0.09

$1.6

$0.56

$1.1

2032

$0.12

$2.2

$0.77

$1.5

$0.09

$1.5

$0.53

$1.0

2033

$0.12

$2.1

$0.75

$1.5

$0.08

$1.4

$0.49

$1.0

2034

$0.12

$2.0

$0.73

$1.4

$0.07

$1.3

$0.46

$0.91

2035

$0.11

$2.0

$0.71

$1.4

$0.07

$1.2

$0.43

$0.85

2036

$0.11

$1.9

$0.69

$1.4

$0.07

$1.1

$0.40

$0.80

2037

$0.11

$1.9

$0.67

$1.3

$0.06

$1.1

$0.38

$0.74

2038

$0.10

$1.8

$0.65

$1.3

$0.06

$1.0

$0.35

$0.70

2039

$0.10

$1.8

$0.63

$1.2

$0.05

$0.9

$0.33

$0.65

2040

$0.10

$1.7

$0.61

$1.2

$0.05

$0.9

$0.31

$0.61

Note: Discounted to 2022

9-3


-------
Table 9-4: Discounted Costs, Proposed Options, for MAC ! R, 2026-2040 ($2019)

3 percent

7 percent

Year

Annualized Costs

Revenue from Product

Annualized Costs (with

Annualized Costs

Revenue from

Annualized Costs

(w/o Revenue)

Recovery

Revenue)

(w/o Revenue)

Product Recovery

(with Revenue)

2026

$2.8

$0.92

$1.9

$2.4

$0.79

$1.6

2027

$2.7

$0.90

$1.8

$2.2

$0.74

$1.5

2028

$2.6

$0.87

$1.8

$2.1

$0.69

$1.4

2029

$2.6

$0.84

$1.7

$2.0

$0.65

$1.3

2030

$2.5

$0.82

$1.7

$1.8

$0.60

$1.2

2031

$2.4

$0.80

$1.6

$1.7

$0.56

$1.1

2032

$2.3

$0.77

$1.6

$1.6

$0.53

$1.1

2033

$2.3

$0.75

$1.5

$1.5

$0.49

$1.0

2034

$2.2

$0.73

$1.5

$1.4

$0.46

$0.93

2035

$2.1

$0.71

$1.4

$1.3

$0.43

$0.87

2036

$2.1

$0.69

$1.4

$1.2

$0.40

$0.82

2037

$2.0

$0.67

$1.4

$1.1

$0.38

$0.76

2038

$2.0

$0.65

$1.3

$1.1

$0.35

$0.71

2039

$1.9

$0.63

$1.3

$1.0

$0.33

$0.67

2040

$1.8

$0.61

$1.2

$0.93

$0.31

$0.62

Note: Discounted to 2022

9-4


-------
9.3 GACT 6B

Table 9-5: Discounted Capital and O&M Costs, Proposed Options, for GACT 6B, 2026-2040 ($2019)

3 percent







Operating and

Revenue from

Total Annualized



Operating and

Revenue from

Total Annualized





Cost with
Revenue from



Cost with
Revenue from

Year

Capital Cost

Maintenance

Product

Capital Cost

Maintenance

Product





Cost

Recovery

Product Recovery



Cost

Recovery

Product Recovery

2026

$5.3

$5.3

$17

($6.3)

$4.6

$4.5

$15

($5.4)

2027

$5.2

$5.1

$16

($6.1)

$4.3

$4.2

$14

($5.0)

2028

$5.0

$5.0

$16

($5.9)

$4.0

$4.0

$13

($4.7)

2029

$4.9

$4.8

$15

($5.7)

$3.7

$3.7

$12

($4.4)

2030

$4.7

$4.7

$15

($5.6)

$3.5

$3.5

$11

($4.1)

2031

$4.6

$4.6

$15

($5.4)

$3.3

$3.2

$10

($3.8)

2032

$4.5

$4.4

$14

($5.3)

$3.1

$3.0

$10

($3.6)

2033

$4.3

$4.3

$14

($5.1)

$2.9

$2.8

$9.0

($3.4)

2034

$4.2

$4.2

$13

($5.0)

$2.7

$2.6

$8.4

($3.1)

2035

$4.1

$4.0

$13

($4.8)

$2.5

$2.5

$7.9

($2.9)

2036

$4.0

$3.9

$13

($4.7)

$2.3

$2.3

$7.4

($2.7)

2037

$3.9

$3.8

$12

($4.5)

$2.2

$2.2

$6.9

($2.6)

2038

$3.7

$3.7

$12

($4.4)

$2.0

$2.0

$6.4

($2.4)

2039

$3.6

$3.6

$12

($4.3)

$1.9

$1.9

$6.0

($2.2)

2040

$3.5

$3.5

$11

($4.1)

$1.8

$1.8

$5.6

($2.1)

Note: Discounted to 2022

9-5


-------
Table 9-6: Discounted Costs, Proposed Options, for GACT 6B, 2026-2040 ($2019)

3 percent

7 percent

Year

Annualized Costs

Revenue from Product

Annualized Costs (with

Annualized Costs

Revenue from

Annualized Costs



(w/o Revenue)

Recovery

Revenue)

(w/o Revenue)

Product Recovery

(with Revenue)

2026

$12

$17

($5.2)

$10

$15

($4.5)

2027

$11

$16

($5.1)

$9.4

$14

($4.2)

2028

$11

$16

($4.9)

$8.7

$13

($3.9)

2029

$11

$15

($4.8)

$8.2

$12

($3.7)

2030

$10

$15

($4.7)

$7.6

$11

($3.4)

2031

$10

$15

($4.5)

$7.1

$10

($3.2)

2032

$10

$14

($4.4)

$6.7

$10

($3.0)

2033

$10

$14

($4.3)

$6.2

$9.0

($2.8)

2034

$9.2

$13

($4.1)

$5.8

$8.4

($2.6)

2035

$8.9

$13

($4.0)

$5.4

$7.9

($2.5)

2036

$8.7

$13

($3.9)

$5.1

$7.4

($2.3)

2037

$8.4

$12

($3.8)

$4.8

$6.9

($2.1)

2038

$8.2

$12

($3.7)

$4.4

$6.4

($2.0)

2039

$7.9

$12

($3.6)

$4.2

$6.0

($1.9)

2040

$7.7

$11

($3.5)

$3.9

$5.6

($1.7)

Note: Discounted to 2022

9-6


-------
United States	Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards	Publication No. EPA-452/R-22-002

Environmental Protection	Health and Environmental Impacts Division	June 2022

Agency	Research Triangle Park, NC

1


-------