OAQPS Economic Analysis
Resource Document

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency
Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards
Innovative Strategies and Economics Group

April 1999


-------
This document is intended to be a resource for understanding and performing economic
analyses by OAQPS economists. This document should not be interpreted as guidance that
will be followed exactly by OAQPS in its analyses. Each analysis performed by OAQPS
presents unique features, so this guidance is only advisory in nature. This document will
need to be revised to reflect changes in EPA's approach to implementing statutory or
administrative requirements and to clarify and update text if the document is to continue to be
a helpful resource.

111


-------
iv


-------
TABLE OF CONTENTS

Section	Page

1	Introduction 	1-1

1.1	Regulatory Context 	1-1

1.2	Different Levels of Economic Analysis in OAQPS	1-3

1.2.1 Stages of Analysis: Proposal versus Final Rule 	1-4

1.3	Scope of This Document	1-5

1.4	Organization of This Document	1-6

2	Regulatory Background	2-1

2.1	OAQPS's Regulatory Authority 	2-1

2.2	Statutory and Administrative Requirements for Economic

Analysis of Regulations	2-2

2.2.1	Clean Air Act	2-4

2.2.2	Executive Order 12866 	 2-5

2.2.3	Statutes and Executive Orders Requiring "Impact Analysis" . . 2-6

2.2.3.1	Impacts on State, Local, and Tribal Governments ...	2-11

2.2.3.2	Small Entity Impacts 	2-12

2.2.3.3	Reporting and Recordkeeping Requirements	2-13

2.2.3.4	Impacts on Children	2-14

2.2.3.5	Impacts on Low-Income and Minority

Populations	2-15

2.3	Summary 	2-16

3	The Regulatory Development Process	3-1

3.1 EPA Regulatory Development Process	3-1

3.1.1	Start Action Notice 	3-3

3.1.2	Workgroup Formation	3-3

3.1.3	Early Guidance from Senior Management	3-4

3.1.4	Analytical Blueprint	3-4

v


-------
TABLE OF CONTENTS (CONTINUED)

Section	Page

3.1.5	Preliminary Analysis, Regulatory Options Development,

and Selection of Alternatives	3-4

3.1.6	Rule Preparation and Workgroup Closure	3-5

3.1.7	OMB Review	3-6

3.1.8	Administrator's Signature and FR Publication ofProposed

Rule 	3-6

3.1.9	Public Comment, Rule Revision, and Signature and
Publication ofProposed Rule	3-7

3.1.10	Rule Revision, Signature, and Publication of the Final Rule . . 3-7

3.2	Economic Analysis in Regulatory Development	3-7

3.2.1	Overview of Analysis Activity	3-7

3.2.2	A Note on Cost/Control Strategy Analysis for NAAQS 	3-9

3.2.3	Structure and Content of ISEG Reports	3-11

3.3	Specific ISEG Tasks in the Regulatory Development Process 	3-13

3.3.1	Initial Screening	3-13

3.3.2	Scoping Assessment and SBREFA Determination	3-14

3.3.3	Industry Profile	3-15

3.3.4	Analysis Plan	3-15

3.3.5	Analysis	3-16

3.3.6	Technical Support Documents	3-17

4 Industry Profile Development 	4-1

4.1	Purpose and Use	4-1

4.2	Structure and Content 	4-2

4.3	Data Sources 	4-6

4.3.1	The Supply Side	4-9

4.3.2	The Demand Side	4-12

4.3.3	Industry Organization	4-13

4.3.3.1	Market Structure	4-15

4.3.3.2	Manufacturing Plants	4-15

4.3.3.3	Firm Characterization	4-17

4.3.3.4	Other Owning Entities 	4-23

4.3.4	Markets 	4-24

vi


-------
TABLE OF CONTENTS (CONTINUED)

Section	Page

5 EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues	 5-1

5.1	Alternative Approaches for Economic Impact Analysis	 5-2

5.1.1	Behavioral vs. Nonbehavioral Models	 5-2

5.1.2	Market Model Scope: Partial vs. General Equilibrium	 5-3

5.1.3	Length-of-Run Considerations	 5-4

5.1.3.1	VeryShortRun 		5-4

5.1.3.2	LongRun		5-5

5.1.3.3	"Intermediate" Run 		5-6

5.1.4	Static vs. Dynamic Models 		5-7

5.1.5	Standard Approach for ISEG Industry-Level Analyses 		5-8

5.2	PEIS Modeling Approach: Conceptual Framework 	 5-8

5.2.1	Facility-Level Effects	 5-9

5.2.2	Market Effects 	 5-11

5.2.3	Facility-Level Response to Compliance Costs and

New Market Prices	 5-12

5.3	PEIS Modeling Approach: Operational Issues	 5-15

5.3.1	Baseline Characterization 	 5-15

5.3.1.1	Producer Characterization 		5-16

5.3.1.2	Market Characterization		5-18

5.3.1.3	Characterizing Impacts Outside a Market Setting .. .	5-20

5.3.2	Regulatory Control Costs 		5-21

5.3.3	Modeling Economic Behavior		5-23

5.3.3.1	Supply Characterization and Responses 	 5-25

5.3.3.2	Demand Characterization and Responses 	 5-34

5.3.3.3	Determine With-Regulation Equilibrium	 5-37

5.4	Economic Impact Results	 5-37

5.4.1	Market-Level Results 		5-38

5.4.2	Industry-Level Results		5-38

5.4.3	Company-Level Impacts		5-43

5.4.4	Community-Level Impacts 		5-44

5.4.5	Social Costs of the Regulation		5-45

5.4.5.1	Producer and Consumer Surplus Measures	 5-46

5.4.5.2	Other Elements of Social Costs 	 5-49

vii


-------
TABLE OF CONTENTS (CONTINUED)

Section	Page

6	Impact Analyses	6-1

6.1	The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act (UMRA) 	6-1

6.2	The Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA) and Small Business

Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act (SBREFA)	6-4

6.3	The Paperwork Reduction Act (PRA)	6-10

6.4	Distributional Impacts 	6-12

6.5 Structural Impacts 	6-14

7	Framework for Quantitative Benefits Analysis	7-1

7.1	Economic Benefits: An Overview 	7-2

7.2	Steps in Conducting Benefits Analysis 	7-4

7.2.1	Identifying Benefits 	7-4

7.2.2	Quantifying Benefits 	7-7

7.2.2.1	Quantifying Health Benefits	7-7

7.2.2.2	Quantifying Ecological Benefits	7-10

7.2.2.3	Quantifying Benefits through Nonliving Systems ... 7-11

7.2.3	Monetizing Benefits	7-11

7.2.3.1	Monetizing Health Benefits	7-12

7.2.3.2	Monetizing Ecological Benefits and Benefits to
Materials and Structures	7-18

7.2.3.3	Benefit Values per Unit of Emissions 	7-20

7.3	Benefits Transfer	7-23

8	General Methodological Issues 	8-1

8.1 Specifying the Time Period of Analysis 	8-1

viii


-------
TABLE OF CONTENTS (CONTINUED)

Section	Page

8.2	Specifying a Baseline for Analysis 	8-3

8.2.1	Forecasting Economic Activity in the Absence of the
Regulation 	8-4

8.2.2	Assessing the Rate of Compliance with Existing Regulations .8-5

8.2.3	Anticipating Future Regulatory Actions by Other Federal
Agencies, by Other Offices within the Agency, and by State,

Local, and Tribal Governments	8-6

8.2.4	Anticipating Nonregulatory Factors	8-7

8.2.5	Developing a Starting Point for the Baseline	8-7

8.3	Discounting Benefits and Costs	8-8

8.3.1	Basic Considerations in Discounting	8-9

8.3.1.1	Discounting and Private Decisions	8-9

8.3.1.2	Discounting and Public Policy Decisions	8-11

8.3.2	The Two-Stage Discounting Procedure	8-13

8.3.3	Discounting Issues Deserving Further Attention:

Nonmonetized Benefits and Long Time Horizons 	8-16

8.3.4	Discount Rates and the Capital Costs of the Regulation	8-17

8.3.4.1	Conceptual Issues	8-18

8.3.4.2	Estimating Capital Costs in Economic Impact

Analysis 	8-19

8.3.4.3	Reconciling Social Costs in an EIA with "True"

Social Costs 	8-21

8.3.4.4	Practical Concerns for the Policymaker and Analyst . 8-26

8.3.5	Empirical Evidence on Discount Rates	8-28

8.3.5.1	Consumption Rate of Interest	8-28

8.3.5.2	Rate of Return on Private Capital	8-29

8.3.6	Discounting Recommendations	8-29

8.4	Addressing Uncertainty	8-30

9 Communicating the Results of the Economic Analysis	9-1

9.1 Communication Goals, the Audience, and Challenges 	9-2

IX


-------
TABLE OF CONTENTS (CONTINUED)

Section	Page

9.2	Key Principles of Clear and Effective Communication	9-3

9.3	A Note on Visual Communication	9-7

References 	R-l

x


-------
LIST OF FIGURES

Section	Page

2-1	Sequence of Questions for Determining the Necessary Impact

Analyses	 2-10

3-1	EPA Regulatory Development Process	 3-2

3-2 Flow of Analytical Information in Regulatory Development	 3-8

3-3	Main Activities Within ISEG in the Regulatory Development Process	 3-14

4-1	Possible Ownership Configurations in U.S. Industries	 4-18

5-1	Full-Cost Pass-Through of Regulatory Costs 	 5-5

5-2 Partial-Cost Pass-Through of Regulatory Costs 	 5-7

5-3 Product Supply Function at Facility 	 5-10

5-4 Effect of Compliance Costs on Product Supply Function at Facility 	 5-11

5-5 Market Equilibrium Without and With Regulation 	 5-13

5-6 Actual and Annualized Estimates of Compliance Costs	 5-24

5-7 Horizontal Supply Curve 	 5-26

5-8 Upward-Sloping Supply Curve	 5-28

5-9 Step Supply Function	 5-29

5-10 Regulation-Induced Cost Shifts by Supply Characterization 	 5-33

5-11 Demand Curves	 5-35

5-12	Sensitivity of Changes in Producer and Consumer Surplus to the

Elasticity of Demand (Elasticity of Supply =1.0)	 5-36

5-13 Market Outcomes with Nonparallel Supply Shift 	 5-40

5-14	Economic Welfare Changes with Regulation: Consumer

and Producer Surplus 	 5-48

7-1 Functional Relationships in Benefits Analysis 	 7-3

7-2	Functional Relationships Between NOx Emissions and Environmental

Service Flows	 7-6

9-1 Net Benefits of Regulatory Alternatives	 9-8

XI


-------
LIST OF TABLES

Section	Page

1-1	Information Provided by Different Types of OAQPS Economic

Analyses	 1-3

2-1	Statutes and Executive Orders Requiring Economic Analyses	2-3

2-2 Economic Analysis Requirements Under EO 12291 and EO 12866 	 2-7

4-1 Annotated Industry Profile Outline	4-3

4-2 List of Industries with EPA Sector Notebooks	4-8

4-3 Summary of Sources for Supply-Side Characterization	 4-11

4-4 Summary of Sources for Demand-Side Characterization	 4-14

4-5 Data Elements for Facility-Specific Sources	 4-16

4-6 Summary of Company-Specific Sources	 4-19

4-7 Data Elements for Company-Specific Sources 	 4-20

4-8 Summary of Sources to Characterize Other Owning Entities	 4-25

4-9	Summary of Market-Level Data Sources 	 4-26

5-1	Baseline Characterization of U.S. Amino and Phenolic Resin

Markets: 1991	 5-16

5-2 Required Compliance Cost Elements for Affected Entities 	 5-22

5-3 Summary of Market-Level Impacts of the Proposed Polymers and

Resins III NESHAP: 1991	 5-39

5-4 Summary of National-Level Industry Impacts of the Proposed Polymers

and Resins III NESHAP: 1991	 5-40

5-5 Distribution of Industry-Level Impacts of Proposed NESHAP by

Affected and Unaffected Producers: 1991	 5-42

5-6	Distribution of Social Costs Associated with the Proposed Polymers

and Resins III NESHAP: 1991	 5-47

6-1	Recommended Quantitative Criteria for Evaluating the Economic Impact

of a Rule on Small Entities 	 6-6

6-2 Summary of Quantitative Information Used to Identify Applicable

Categories 	 6-8

6-3	Contents of the Supporting Statement for an Information Collection

Request 	 6-11

7-1	Applicability of Valuation Methods to Assess Categories of Ecological

Benefits 	 7-19

xii


-------
Section

LIST OF TABLES (CONTINUED)

Page

7-2 Examples of Estimated Value per Mg for Selected Pollutants (1996$) 	7-21

7-3	Estimates of the Global Social Costs of Greenhouse Gas Emissions 	7-22

8-1	Transformation of Social Costs from an EIA to BCA	8-30

9-1	Identified, Quantified, and Monetized Health Effects	9-5

9-2 Sample Table of Net Benefits Estimates—Annual Net Benefits of

Regulatory Options 	9-6

Xlll


-------
Section 1 — Introduction

SECTION 1
INTRODUCTION

This document provides guidance on the preparation of economic analyses (EAs) in
the Innovative Strategies and Economics Group (ISEG) of the U.S. Environmental Protection
Agency's (EPA's) Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards (OAQPS). It is written for
analysts who conduct these analyses and for other parties seeking information on their
purpose, analytical requirements, and recommended methods. The current document updates
its predecessor, "Analytical Methods Manual" (January 1985). The update reflects changes
since 1985 in statutory and administrative requirements for EAs, regulatory procedures at
EPA, and methodological developments relevant to EAs of environmental regulations.
Notable among these changes is the issuance of Executive Order (EO) 12866—Regulatory
Planning and Review, which establishes the foundation for performing EAs of Federal
regulations.1

1.1 Regulatory Context

OAQPS establishes standards and regulations to improve the nation's air quality
subject to the provisions of the Clean Air Act (CAA). Specific provisions of the CAA
require that an economic impact assessment (EIA) be conducted for individual regulatory
actions under the Act's authority. Requirements for economic analysis can be viewed in the
broader context of overarching requirements for all Federal regulations as stipulated by the
presidential executive order on regulatory review. EO 12866 requires regulatory agencies to
submit all proposed and final regulations to the Office of Management and Budget (OMB)
for review. Agencies must demonstrate that the regulation is necessary and that the potential
benefits of the intended regulation justify its costs. For any "significant regulatory action,"2

'President Clinton issued EO 12866 on September 30, 1993. EO 12866 is similar in purpose to, and
supersedes, EO 12291 issued by President Reagan in 1981. Key differences between these EOs are
highlighted in Section 2 of this document.

2The definition of a significant regulatory action is discussed in Section 2 of this document.

1-1


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

the Agency is required to prepare a comprehensive EA, which contains descriptions of the
benefits and costs of the proposed rule and of alternative approaches.

In the past, as stipulated in EO 12291, the comprehensive set of analyses sent to OMB
for review was referred to as a "regulatory impact analysis (RIAs)." EO 12866 replaced
EO 12291 and simply requires that benefits, costs, and other economic impacts be examined.
Since EO 12866 did not provide a specific name for these reports, the naming convention has
become somewhat loose. Therefore, even though the term RIA is still widely used
throughout the Agency and OMB, the term "Economic Analysis (EA)" will be used in this
document to refer to the assessment of benefits, costs, and other impacts required by EO
12866. The key point to be made here is that, whichever term is used, the analyses called for
under EO 12866 are broader in scope than an EIA. The analyses include an assessment of
benefits in quantified and monetized terms when possible and a comparison of benefits and
costs to address the "cost justification" issue just described. The notion, under EO 12866,
that a rule's benefits must justify its costs is a less restrictive requirement than existed in the
predecessor, EO 12291, wherein benefits must be shown to exceed costs for the regulation to
proceed. EO 12866 and EO 12291 are further contrasted in Section 2 of this document. It is
important to recognize that EO 12866 does not supercede the authority to regulate under the
CAA or any other statutory authority. EO 12866 cannot, for instance, negate a regulation
based on benefit-cost criteria if the statutory authority precludes that from affecting the
regulatory decision.

The regulatory context of OAQPS regulations and the corresponding requirements for
economic analysis change through time as legislation and administrative policies are updated
in response to a myriad of societal forces. For example, in the 5 years immediately preceding
the preparation of this document, the White House has issued a number of EOs affecting the
nature and scope of EAs performed in support of Federal regulations. In addition, Congress
has adopted legislation requiring specific forms of economic impacts be analyzed and
considered in the design of Federal regulation. Other legislation affecting economic analysis
requirements is pending, though not necessarily assured of passage. In short, the regulatory
background described here provides a snapshot of the situation in early 1999. The reader is
advised to recognize these dynamics and to remain current with changes in the regulatory
environment that determine the requirements for economic analysis.

1-2


-------
Section 1 — Introduction

1.2 Different Levels of Economic Analysis in OAQPS

Economic analysis of proposed rulemakings in OAQPS can be viewed as part of a
hierarchical process:

•	preliminary screening assessment,

•	EIA, and

•	EA.

The information generated by each of these analyses is summarized in Table 1-1.

Table 1-1. Information Provided by Different Types of OAQPS Economic Analyses

Information Preliminary Screening
Provided Assessment

Economic Impact
Assessment (EIA)

Economic Analysis (EA)a

Costs Qualitative or rough estimate
of compliance costs

Size and distribution of
social costs

Size and distribution of
social costs

Benefits Qualitative or rough estimate



Size and distribution of
social benefits

Market outcomes

Price effects

Price effects



Quantity effects

Quantity effects



International trade
effects

International trade
effects

Distributional
consequences

Distribution of social
costs across society

Distribution of social costs
across society



Small business impacts

Small business impacts



State and local
governmental imports

State and local
governmental imports

Benefit and cost impacts on
sensitive populations

Other

Energy consumption



a Previously referred to as Regulatory Impact Analysis (RIA).

1-3


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

The purpose of the preliminary screening assessment is to obtain an initial read on the
potential magnitude of the regulation's economic impact. This assessment may be somewhat
qualitative in nature or may employ relatively limited data and other information to provide
first-order quantitative estimates of impacts. When the initial assessment suggests a
relatively small impact, ISEG can use this information to direct its analytical resources
toward other regulations that are likely to have a larger impact. Those regulations will move
up to the next tier and be targeted for a full EIA, which will provide a broader and deeper
assessment of cost impacts of the rule. For "significant regulatory actions" as stipulated
under EO 12866, a full EA is conducted. For all intents and purposes, an EA may employ the
EIA as the basis for its cost estimates and augment the analysis with a benefits assessment
and comparison of benefits and costs and evaluation of their distribution as required under
EO 12866 and other mandates and legislation.

1.2.1 Stages of Analysis: Proposal versus Final Rule

Prior to rule proposal, the analysis will compare costs, impacts, and—in the case of an
EA—benefits of the different regulatory alternatives being proposed. This is often referred to
as the "proposal" draft. After taking into consideration public comments, the Agency may
narrow the focus to the selected regulatory alternative. Consequently, the analysis that is
prepared at the final stage rule (promulgation) will typically produce analytical results to
support the selected regulatory option. This is often referred to as the "final" draft. EO
12866, however, does require the analysis to address the reasons for selecting the final rule
over alternative regulatory and nonregulatory approaches. Therefore, some elements of the
earlier analyses may be incorporated in the final draft to address these concerns. While not
explicitly required in the EIA provisions of the CAA, some discussion of the selected
regulatory option versus its alternatives in the final EIA report may help demonstrate how
economic analysis was used to inform the rule selection decision.

The purpose of the final EA for significant regulatory actions is to demonstrate that
the rule selected by EPA decisionmakers complies with the requirements of EO 12866. The
final EA (RIA) must present the economic rationale for the proposed rule, the justification for
regulatory intervention, the rationale for the particular regulatory requirements being
proposed, the benefits and costs of the selected regulatory option, and the impacts of the
proposed rule on specific entities or population groups. The final EA draws heavily from the
preliminary EA to justify the proposed rule.

1-4


-------
Section 1 — Introduction

1.3 Scope of This Document

This guidance document discusses the contents and preparation of a full EA. As
indicated above, the EA can be viewed as an expanded EIA—one that includes a benefits
assessment and benefit-cost comparison. Therefore, while the document is designed to cover
all aspects of an EA, by definition it also addresses the EIA, which is a subset of the larger
analysis. Proposal and final assessments overlap significantly and, therefore, have a
common structure that will be presented here. However, there are important differences in
the purpose of the proposal and final assessments and the stage in the rule development
process at which each is prepared. These differences and the implications for their
preparation will be emphasized throughout this document.

This document also presents further background information on the CAA, EO 12866,
and other statutes and EOs imposing analytical requirements. Recommended analytical
methods and other practical issues that arise in conducting these analyses are also discussed.
This information provides a broader understanding of the role of economic analysis in the
regulatory process and ways the analysis can better inform that process.

Several issues relevant to economic analysis in ISEG are beyond the scope of this
document. The following topics do not receive detailed treatment in this document, but they
are important for the analyst to consider in performing these assessments:

•	theoretical foundations of welfare economics and benefit-cost analysis,

•	analysis of information collection requirements, and

•	document style and formatting.

This guidance document is a companion to several other guidance documents
available to ISEG staff, including

•	Economic Analysis of Federal Regulations Under Executive Order 12866, Office
of Management and Budget, January 11 1996;

•	EPA Interim Guidance for Implementing the Small Business Regulatory
Enforcement Fairness Act and Related Provisions of the Regulatory Flexibility
Act, EPA SBREFA Task Force, February 5, 1997;

•	Interim Guidance for Incorporating Environmental Justice Concerns in EPA 's
NEPA Compliance Analyses, EPA Office of Federal Activities, September 30,
1997;

1-5


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

•	Unfunded Mandates Guidance, EPA Office of Regulatory Management and
Evaluation, August 11, 1995;

•	Engineering Inputs for the Economic Impact Analysis. Office of Air Quality,
Planning, and Standards, Innovative Strategies and Economics Group. July 1997;
and

•	Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses. EPA, Office of Policy. Draft
under revision in fall 1998.

Because the issues addressed in these documents tend to evolve, analysts should ensure that
they have the most recent guidance on these issues. Although this document does overlap to
some extent with the other guidance documents, its primary purpose is to address analytical
and procedural issues specific to preparing economic assessments in OAQPS. Readers
should refer to the other guidance documents for more detailed information on the specific
statute or EO and its analytical requirements.

1.4 Organization of This Document

The remainder of this document is organized as follows:

•	Section 2 presents background information on the rationale and criteria for EAs
stipulated in the CAA and EO 12866, as well as the rationale and criteria put forth
in a variety of statutes and EOs requiring various forms of "impact" analysis.

•	Section 3 provides an overview of the regulatory development process both at the
Agency level and for OAQPS/ISEG.

•	Section 4 addresses the preparation of industry profiles, including their structure,
connections between the industry profile and economic analysis, and listing of
commonly used data sources.

•	Section 5 presents the analytical framework and operational issues for estimating
the social costs and direct economic impacts of the rule in an EIA.

•	Section 6 addresses methodological issues for conducting various distributional
impact analyses subject to administrative and statutory requirements.

•	Section 7 presents the analytical framework and discussion of practical issues
involved in estimating environmental benefits of a regulation.

1-6


-------
Section 1 — Introduction

•	Section 8 discusses several key general methodological and policy issues, such as
the establishment of a regulatory baseline, discounting procedures, and methods
for addressing uncertainty.

•	Section 9 recommends ways to communicate EA results so that they are
transparent and understandable to decisionmakers.

1-7


-------
Section 2 — Regulatory Background

SECTION 2
REGULATORY BACKGROUND

Several statutes and EOs are fundamental to the various forms of economic analysis
performed in ISEG. This section describes the statutory authority under which all air quality
regulations and standards are implemented by OAQPS: the Clean Air Act (CAA). It
discusses the analytical requirements for economic analysis under the CAA, reviews the
broader requirements for economic analysis of significant regulatory actions under EO
12866, and discusses several relatively new (as of mid-1998) statutes and EOs designed to
supplement traditional EAs with what is broadly defined as "impact analysis."

2.1 OAQPS's Regulatory Authority

The purpose of the CAA is to establish, implement, and maintain standards for the
nation's air quality. Since its inception the CAA has been amended several times, most
recently in 1990. Pursuant to the 1990 Amendments, the CAA vests EPA with the authority
to undertake the following actions:

•	set national ambient air quality standards (NAAQS) for six "criteria" pollutants;

•	establish national emissions standards for 188 listed hazardous air pollutants
(NESHAP);

•	establish new source performance standards (NSPS), imposing technology-based
requirements on new or modified major sources of pollutants;

•	establish emission standards for mobile sources;

•	impose requirements to address specific air pollution problems, such as acid rain
and depletion of stratospheric ozone;

•	establish nonattainment areas for regions that have failed to meet the NAAQS
standards for one or more of the criteria pollutants; and

2-1


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

• require each State to submit a plan for the implementing and enforcing national
standards, thus referred to as State Implementation Plans (SIP). Also required
within each SIP are measures to ensure against significant deterioration of air
quality in areas that meet NAAQS standards.

In addition to possessing the legal authority to regulate, OAQPS is also required to
examine efforts to deregulate or reverse previous rulemakings if they are found to be
unwarranted by the underlying statutory authority. The move to consider deregulation
follows from the Office of the Vice President's National Performance Review, often referred
to as the "Reinventing Government" initiative.

EPA's regulations are designed to directly change the behavior of those entities whose
activities result in the generation and release of air pollutants. These regulations are typically
in the form of administrative controls (so-called "command and control" policies) that
prescribe certain emitter behaviors (e.g., require the installation of stack gas scrubbers) or that
set standards on the allowable releases of pollutants and allow polluters to determine how to
achieve the standard. However, they may also take the form of market-type instruments
(e.g., emission charges or transferrable rights) that are designed to induce certain behavioral
responses by changing emitters' consequences of a given action. Finally, and less frequently,
EPA's actions may be simply informational, designed to inform entities about the benefits or
costs of their current or alternative behaviors (e.g., pollution prevention).

EPA's emission guidelines are developed to provide state and other governmental
entities with guidance regarding the methods that may be used to achieve air quality
objectives. In a sense, therefore, guidelines are an example of an informational policy. The
information, in turn, may be used by the states and other authorities to develop
administrative, market-type, or information policies of their own to address their air pollution
problems and their responsibilities under the CAA. Changes in the behavior of emitters in
response to federal or state level regulations will create economic impacts as resources are
reallocated toward more environmental protection and as emissions are reduced.

2.2 Statutory and Administrative Requirements for Economic Analysis of

Regulations

Regulatory agencies conduct economic analyses of potential regulatory actions to
inform decisionmakers about the effects of the regulation on society's current and future
well-being. In addition to informing decisionmakers within the Agency, economic analyses
are conducted to meet the statutory and administrative requirements imposed by Congress

2-2


-------
Section 2 — Regulatory Background

and the Executive Office. The statutes and EOs requiring economic analyses are listed in
Table 2-1. For the purposes of this discussion, we distinguish between analyses in which
both benefits and costs are estimated and compared ("benefit-cost analysis") and analyses
that focus on the size and distribution of economic impacts among specific groups in society
("impact analysis").

Table 2-1. Statutes and Executive Orders Requiring Economic Analyses

Benefit-Cost Analysis

Impact Analysis

Statutes Periodic assessment of

Economic impact assessment of specific

costs and benefits of the

standards and regulations under the CAA

CAA (CAA Section 812)

(CAA Section 317)



Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA)



Small Business Regulatory Enforcement



Fairness Act (SBREFA)



Unfunded Mandates Reform Act



(UMRA)



Paperwork Reduction Act (PRA)



Foreign trade impacts (CAA



Section 813)

Executive Orders EO 12866: Regulatory

EO 12866: Regulatory Planning and

Planning and Review

Review



EO 12875: Enhancing the



Intergovernmental Partnership



EO 12898: Federal Actions to Address



Environmental Justice in Minority



Populations and Low-Income



Populations



EO 13045: Protection of Children from



Environmental Health Risks and Safety



Risks

2-3


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Statutory requirements for economic analysis are often included in the language of the
statute granting the Agency regulatory authority in a particular area. For example, the CAA
requires EPA to perform a benefit-cost analysis of the entire CAA program on a periodic
basis. In addition, the White House, through EO 12866, requires Executive Branch agencies
to perform benefit-cost analyses of all rules it deems to be "significant"1 and to submit these
analyses to the OMB for review.

In addition to benefit-cost analysis, impact analyses are required in certain
circumstances by both statutes and EOs. Of key importance for ISEG, the CAA requires that
the cost and economic impacts (though not necessarily benefits) be estimated for specific
regulations and standards proposed under the authority of the Act. This is the core purpose of
the EIA reports described in Section 1. In addition, the Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA), as
amended by the Small Business Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act of 1996 (SBREFA),
requires EPA to give special consideration to the effect of Federal regulations on small
entities and to consider regulatory options that might mitigate any such impacts. EO 12875
(Enhancing the Intergovernmental Partnership) and the Unfunded Mandates Reform Act
(UMRA) of 1995 require agencies to evaluate the impact of their regulatory actions on State,
local, and tribal governments.

The analytical requirements are now discussed in more detail and in correspondence
with the underlying statutory or administrative authority.

2.2.1 Clean Air Act

Section 312 of the CAA requires the EPA Administrator to conduct a "comprehensive
analysis of the impact of the [CAA] on the public health, economy, and environment of the
United States. In performing such analysis, the Administrator should consider the costs,
benefits, and other factors associated with compliance...." This provision requires periodic
assessment of the overall contribution of the CAA to society's welfare. However,

Section 317 of the CAA requires that an EIA be performed for individual rulemakings under
the Act's authority. For each proposed standard or regulation, the EIA will, to the extent
practicable, include an analysis of the following impacts:

'A regulation is generally determined to be significant if it is expected to result in a substantial impact on the
economy. The definition of a significant regulatory action is discussed in detail in Section 2.1.2 of this
section.

2-4


-------
Section 2 — Regulatory Background

•	costs of compliance,

•	potential inflationary or recessionary effects,

•	effects on competition with respect to small businesses,

•	effects on consumer costs, and

•	effects on energy use.

Notably absent from the list is an assessment of benefits or comparison of benefits and costs.
Moreover, CAA Section 317 clearly states that the EIA shall not" be construed to alter the
basis on which a standard or regulation is promulgated ... preclude the Administrator from
carrying out his responsibility ... to protect public health and welfare, or ... require any judicial
review" (CAA §312[e]). Thus, an EIA is used to inform the regulatory process, but its
findings are not strictly binding on the actions the Agency can take.

2.2.2 Executive Order 12866

In support of a rulemaking under EO 12866, regulatory agencies such as EPA must
conduct an analysis of the benefits and costs of a proposed significant regulatory action. The
analysis should organize information in a way that allows comparison of the benefits and
costs of alternative regulatory approaches. As indicated in Section 1, this report is referred to
here as an economic analysis (EA).

In various forms, EAs have been prepared in support of agency rulemakings for many
years. It was not until 1981, however, when President Reagan signed EO 12291, that the
Executive Office sought to determine the cumulative effect of the increasing amount of
regulation being promulgated by various regulatory agencies under a growing number of
statutory authorities. With the signing of EO 12291 the use and importance of economic
assessments of the consequences of regulation increased. EO 12291 defined rules as either
"major" or "nonmajor," based on their potential economic impacts. To assess these impacts,
agencies were required to prepare analyses showing the implications of their regulations. For
major rules, EO 12291 required the agencies to submit an RIA to OMB for review.

On September 30, 1993, the Clinton Administration rescinded EO 12291 and replaced
it with EO 12866. Similar to EO 12291, EO 12866 requires centralized review of regulations
by OMB; however, it changed many of the criteria on which regulatory review was based. In
particular, EO 12866 does not categorize rules as major and nonmajor, but rather as

2-5


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

significant and nonsignificant. The effect of this change in terminology is to expand the
range of rules that require some level of economic analysis subject to OMB review. In
particular, EO 12291 considered any rule major if it was likely to have a substantial economic
impact. EO 12866, however, includes not only economic impact criteria in determining
which rules are significant, but also any Federal regulatory action that may interfere with
State, local, or tribal governments; any regulation that may interfere with regulatory actions
being undertaken by another Federal agency; and any rulemaking that raises a novel legal or
policy issue. As a result of the scope of this definition, OMB has broad powers to review and
request revisions to all regulatory proposals to ensure their consistency with the regulatory
principles contained in the Order.

EO 12866 also changed the fundamental basis on which Agency rulemakings are
evaluated. In particular, EO 12291 required that "regulatory action shall not be undertaken
unless the potential benefits to society for the regulation outweigh (emphasis added) the
potential costs to society," thereby requiring a strict benefit-cost approach to evaluating
regulations (EO 12291 Section 2[b]). In contrast, EO 12866 requires that the Agency
"shall...propose or adopt a regulation only upon reasoned determination that the benefits of
the intended regulation justify (emphasis added) its costs," thereby including benefit-cost
analysis among a number of inputs to the regulatory decisionmaking process (EO 12866,
Section l[b][c]). The difference between these two statements indicates a recognition by the
Clinton Administration that sound regulatory decisions involve a wide range of
considerations and that not all benefits and costs resulting from a regulatory action are easily
expressed in monetary terms. Because many of the previous analyses of major (significant)
rules performed by ISEG (and its predecessor groups) were based on EO 12291, Table 2-2
compares the economic analysis requirements under EO 12291 and EO 12866. The purpose
is to highlight key differences between the types of information provided in the previous
analyses and those now required.

2.2.3 Statutes and Executive Orders Requiring "Impact Analysis"

"Impact analysis" is a general term used to describe various analyses that are
supplemental to the estimates of total benefits and costs. For the purposes of this discussion,
these supplemental impacts are separate from the "cost and economic impacts" addressed in
an EIA.

2-6


-------
Section 2 — Regulatory Background

Table 2-2. Economic Analysis Requirements Under EO 12291 and EO 12866

Which Rules Require Economic Analysis?

EO 12291

EO 12866

"Maior" rules require economic analysis:

"Significant" reeulatorv actions require

A major rule is any regulation that is likely

to result in:

1.	An annual effect on the economy of
$100 million or more;

2.	A major increase in the costs or prices
for consumers, individual industries,
Federal, State, or local government
agencies, or geographic regions; or

3.	Significant adverse effects on
competition, employment, investment,
productivity, innovation, or on the
ability of United States-based
enterprises to compete with foreign-
based enterprises in domestic or export
markets.

economic analysis:

A significant regulatory action is any
regulatory action that is likely to result in a
rule that may:

Have an annual effect on the economy of
$100 million or more or adversely affect in
a material way the economy, a sector of the
economy, productivity, competition, jobs,
the environment, public health or safety, or
State, local, or tribal governments or
communities;2

(continued)

2EO 12866 defines a significant regulatory action as one that either meets the $100 million material adverse
effects criterion stipulated here or one of three other nonquantitative criteria (see Section 3f of EO 12866).
However, the OMB guidance for EAs under EO 12866 stipulates that a full EA (benefit-cost analysis) is
required only when the $100 million/material adverse effect criterion is met.

2-7


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Table 2-2. Economic Analysis Requirements Under EO 12291 and EO 12866 (continued)
What Analyses are Required?

EO 12291

An RIA is required:

Regulatory Impact Analysis... contains[ing]

the following:

1.	A description of the potential benefits of
the rule, including any beneficial effects
that cannot be quantified in monetary
terms, and the identification of those
likely to receive the benefits;

2.	A description of the potential costs of
the rule, including any adverse effects
that cannot be quantified in monetary
terms, and the identification of those
likely to bear the costs;

3.	A determination of the potential net
benefits of the rule, including an
evaluation of effects that cannot be
quantified in monetary terms;

4.	A description of alternative approaches
that could substantially achieve the
same regulatory goal at lower cost,
together with an analysis of this [sic]
potential benefit [sic] and costs and a
brief explanation of the legal reasons
why such alternatives, if proposed,
could not be adopted...

EO 12866

An EA is required:

An assessment of the potential costs and
benefits of the regulatory action.. .the
agency shall also provide to the Office of
Information and Regulatory Affairs the
following additional information developed
as part of the agency's decisionmaking
process../

1.	An assessment, including the underlying
analysis, of benefits anticipated from
the regulatory action ...together with, to
the extent feasible, a quantification of
those benefits;

2.	An assessment, including the underlying
analysis, of costs anticipatedfrom the
regulatory action, together with, to the
extent feasible, a quantification of those
costs; and

3.	An assessment, including the underlying
analysis, of costs and benefits of
potentially effective and reasonably
feasible alternatives to the planned
regulation... and an explanation why the
planned action is preferable to the
identified potential alternatives.

a Unlike its predecessor, EO 12866 does not require the development of a separate RIA for review by OMB.
It is clear from the above list of requirements that all analyses required for OMB review should have already
been conducted by the Agency in its development of the regulation.

2-8


-------
Section 2 — Regulatory Background

Impact analyses are usually concerned with examining the types of costs (e.g., direct
compliance costs, administrative costs, and recordkeeping costs) and the distribution of costs
and benefits (e.g., among small businesses and individuals of various race, age, and income
categories). They go beyond a strict benefit-cost analysis to examine various aspects of the
composition and distribution of benefits and costs. While there are many types of impact
analysis, the statutes and EOs listed in Table 2-1 provide the best guidance for the specific
impacts to be evaluated in developing a regulation.

The first set of impacts to be included in an assessment of a regulation are those
specifically cited in EO 12866. Many of these impacts may be addressed in an economic
analysis; however, the analyst may find it desirable to address some of these impacts
separately, depending on the nature of the regulation under consideration. The impact
analysis requirements mentioned in EO 12866 include the impact of the regulation on

•	the efficient functioning of the economy and private markets, including
productivity, employment, and competitiveness;

•	distribution of impacts and equity; and

•	discrimination or bias.

While EO 12866 is quite broad in terms of the impacts that should be evaluated, more
targeted impact analyses are specifically required by statute or administrative decree.

Whether an impact analysis is required will depend on the nature of the regulation.

Figure 2-1 illustrates the process of determining the necessary impact analyses.3

In general, the goal of impact analyses is to supplement an analysis of benefits and
costs and the other information available to decisionmakers on the consequences of selecting
a particular regulatory option for proposal or promulgation. These analyses should not be
taken on their own to indicate any particular option as a preferred option nor to disqualify any
particular option.

3The simple "Yes/No" decisions indicated in Figure 2-1 can be misleading. Typically, some level of screening
analysis is required to determine whether a particular impact analysis is necessary.

2-9


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Decision to Regulate

>

Q

—


>>
03
C
<
u

E
o
c

o

Preliminary Screening Assessment

E.O. 12866: Is the Rulemaking a Significant Regulatory Action?

YES

NO

Benefit-Cost Analysis

Economic Impact Assessment

>
Q

E.O. 12875 & UMRA: Does Regulatory Action have significant impact on
State, local, or tribal governments?

YES

NO

YES

NO

YES

Information Collection Request

NO

E.O. 13045: Does Regulatory Action impact the health or safety of children?

YES

Analysis of impacts on
children's health

NO

E.O. 12898: Does Regulatory Action impact low-income or minority populations?

YES

Analysis of Equity Impacts

Analysis of impacts on State,
local, and tribal governments



Statement of no impact

>





>

f

RFA & SBREFA: Does Regulatory Action have major impact on small entities?

Regulatory Flexibility Analysis



Certify no significant impact

>





>

f

PRA & 5 CFR 1320: Does Regulatory Action result in reporting or
recordkeeping requirements?

Analysis Specifications

Figure 2-1. Sequence of Questions for Determining the Necessary Impact Analyses

2-10


-------
Section 2 — Regulatory Background

2.2.3.1 Impacts on State, Local, and Tribal Governments

EO 12875, Enhancing the Intergovernmental Partnership, signed by President Clinton
on October 26, 1993, requires that

To the extent feasible and permitted by law, no executive
department or agency...shall promulgate any regulation that is not
required by statute and that creates a mandate upon a State, local,
or tribal government, unless:

(1) funds necessary to pay the direct costs incurred by
the State, local, or tribal government in complying
with the mandate are provided by the Federal
Government; or

2) the agency, prior to formal promulgation of
regulations containing the proposed mandate,
provides to the Director of the Office of
Management and Budget a description of the
extent of the agency's prior consultation with
representatives of affected State, local, and tribal
governments, the nature of their concerns, any
written communications submitted to the agency
by such units of government, and the agency's
position supporting the need to issue the regulation
containing the mandate. (Section 1(a))

UMRA expands the coverage of EO 12875 to include regulations that affect the
private sector. EO 12875 applies to all regulations affecting State, local, or tribal
governments; UMRA applies only to regulations including a "Federal mandate that may
result in expenditures by State, local, or tribal governments, in the aggregate, or by the private
sector, of $100,000,000 or more (adjusted annually for inflation) in any one year." UMRA
directs regulatory agencies to prepare a written statement, including a benefit-cost analysis,
for all proposed and final rules including such a mandate. In particular, the statute requires
that the Agency consider a reasonable range of regulatory alternatives and adopt the least
costly, most cost-effective, or least burdensome alternative. Most of these requirements are
already addressed under EO 12866. For additional guidance on conducting an impact

2-11


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

analysis under EO 12875 and UMRA, see the EPA draft Unfunded Mandates Guidance of
August 11, 1993.

2.2.3.2 Small Entity Impacts

The RFA, as amended by SBREFA of 1996, requires Federal regulatory agencies to
determine whether a proposed or final regulation will have a significant impact on a
substantial number of small entities.4'5 In particular, the RFA requires that agencies prepare
an initial regulatory flexibility analysis (IRFA) for a proposed rule and a final regulatory
flexibility analysis (FRFA) for a final rule unless the agency head certifies that the rule will
not have a significant impact on a substantial number of small entities.6 If the agency makes
a "no significant impact" certification, it must support that certification with a factual
explanation.

A major provision in the SBREFA amendments to the RFA is a requirement that EPA
convene a "Small Business Advocacy Review Panel" for any proposed rule for which the
Agency prepares an IRFA. The purpose of the panel is to solicit the input of small
businesses, small governmental jurisdictions, and small nonprofit organizations that are
affected by the rule. EPA's interim SBREFA guidance recommends that the Agency involve
small entities early in the rulemaking process "when their comments and insights can inform
the Agency's thinking about fundamental issues of rule design and scope, as well as more
specific issues posed by the particular regulatory program at issue" (EPA, 1997f, p. 3-1).

Before promulgation, all major rules and any benefit-cost analyses conducted in
support of the rule are subject to congressional review. The definition of a "major rule"
under the RFA is identical to the definition of a "major rule" under EO 12291 and therefore

4According to the RFA, small entities include small businesses, as defined by the Small Business

Administration (SB A), small government jurisdictions, and small nonprofit organizations. For more details
on the definitions of small entities, see EPA Interim Guidance on Implementing the Small Business
Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act and Related Provisions of the Regulatory Flexibility Act (EPA,
1997f).

5For definitions of "significant impact" and "substantial number of small entities," see the SBREFA discussion
in Section 8 of this guidance document.

6 A certification of "no significant impact" in the proposed rule stage does not preclude a FRFA at the final rule
stage, and an IRFA at the proposed rule stage does not preclude a certification of "no significant impact" at
the final rule stage, because information provided through notice-and-comment rulemaking and changes to
the substance of the rule can change the expected impact of the rule between the proposed and final stages.

2-12


-------
Section 2 — Regulatory Background

potentially more narrow than the definition of a "significant regulatory action" under
EO 12866. Under SBREFA, Agency rulemakings are also subject to judicial review.

Before the enactment of SBREFA, EPA policy on the implementation of the RFA
required that a regulatory flexibility analysis be prepared for any rule that would have any
impact on small businesses. According to EPA Interim Guidance for Implementing the Small
Business Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act and Related Provisions of the Regulatory
Flexibility Act, current Agency policy is to implement the RFA as written; that is, "regulatory
flexibility analyses as specified by the RFA will not be required if the Agency certifies that
the rule will not have significant economic impact on a substantial number of small entities."

2.2.3.3 Reporting and Recordkeeping Requirements

In many rulemakings, various recordkeeping, reporting, labeling, testing, and other
requirements are included to help EPA verify compliance with the rule after it has been
promulgated. Under the Paperwork Reduction Act (PRA), the Agency is required to estimate
the "burden hours" associated with the recordkeeping and reporting requirements and to
weigh this burden against the "practical utility" of the information collection. This analysis
must be presented to OMB for review in a standardized document known as an Information
Collection Request (ICR).7'8

The definition of an information collection was expanded with the 1995 amendments
to the PRA. In particular, 5 CFR 1320, the regulation implementing the provisions of the
1995 PRA, defines a collection of information to include "any requirement or request for
persons to obtain, maintain, retain, report, or publicly disclose information" (Section 3(c)).

New to the 1995 amendments to the PRA is the inclusion of third-party reporting
requirements in the definition of an information collection:

Requirements by an agency for a person to obtain or compile
information for the purpose of disclosure to members of the
public or the public at large, through posting, notification,
labeling or similar disclosure requirements constitute the
"collection of information" whenever the same requirement to

7Under the PRA, burden hour estimates and ICRs are not required for paperwork requirements that affect fewer
than ten entities.

8As of this writing, OMB is finalizing guidance on preparing ICRs.

2-13


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

obtain or compile information would be a "collection of
information" if the information were directly provided to the
agency. (5 CFR 1320.3 (c)(2))

Determining the burden hours associated with reporting and recordkeeping provisions
of Agency regulations is a crucial part of the regulatory development process, particularly
when the purpose of the regulation is to codify reporting and recordkeeping requirements.
Without OMB approval of the ICR, EPA cannot legally conduct any collection of
information included in an Agency rulemaking.

The Agency is responsible for preparing estimates of burden hours associated with
recordkeeping and reporting requirements as well as preparing the ICR itself. The group with
primary responsibility for this task (ISEG or other groups within OAQPS) will vary by
project. Burden hours should be estimated in the course of estimating the costs of any
administrative requirements. The burden hour estimates should be clearly summarized in the
impact analysis so that they can be easily incorporated into the ICR.

2.2.3.4 Impacts on Children

On April 21, 1997, President Clinton signed EO 13045, Protection of Children from
Environmental Health Risks and Safety Risks. Under this Order, agencies are required to
conduct certain analyses if a regulatory action is likely to result in a rule that may

(1)	be 'economically significant' under Executive
Order 12866...; and

(2)	concern an environmental health risk or safety risk
that an agency has reason to believe may
disproportionately affect children. (Section 2)

EO 13045 requires two analyses:

(1)	an evaluation of the environmental health or safety
effects of the planned regulation on children; and

(2)	an explanation of why the planned regulation is
preferable to other potentially effective and
reasonably feasible alternatives considered by the
agency. (Section 5)

2-14


-------
Section 2 — Regulatory Background

Although EO 13045 does not explicitly require an analysis of the economic
implications of regulatory impacts on children, the analyses outlined above must be
submitted to OMB, along with the other analyses outlined in this chapter.

2.2.3.5 Impacts on Low-Income and Minority Populations

Equity effects analysis involves examining the distribution of gains and losses
resulting from a regulation and the magnitude of these gains and losses. Such an analysis
should address any significant issues regarding the distribution of gains (who realizes reduced
risk; the firms, industries, or products that have increased sales or profits) and losses (who
bears new costs, reduced sales or profits, or increased risks) in industry and in the population
at large. For a general discussion of conducting an analysis of the distributional effects of a
regulation, see the "white paper" Evaluating the Equity of Environmental Policy Options
Based on the Distribution of Economic Effects: Preliminary Draft (EPA, 1997g).

EO 12898, Federal Actions to Address Environmental Justice in Minority Populations
and Low-Income Populations, encourages the examination of the equity effects of regulatory
actions:

Each Federal agency shall conduct its programs, policies, and
activities that substantially affect human health or the
environment, in a manner that ensures that such programs,
policies, and activities do not have the effect of excluding persons
(including populations) from participation in, denying persons
(including populations) the benefits of, or subjecting persons
(including populations) to discrimination under, such programs,
policies, and activities, because of their race, color, or national
origin. (Section 2)

In response to EPA's Environmental Justice Strategy (EPA, 1995a) dated April 3,
1995, the EPA Office of Federal Activities (OFA) has developed guidance for incorporating
environmental justice goals into the Agency's activities under the National Environmental
Policy Act (NEPA) (EPA, 1997h). Although the OFA guidance does not specifically address
regulatory analysis, it does provide guidance for identifying disproportionately high and
adverse effects of alternative actions and recommends specific methods to analyze the effects
of a regulatory action on minority and low-income populations.

2-15


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

2.3 Summary

As outlined above, the statutory and administrative requirements for economic
analysis of Agency rules are extensive. Economic analyses of most regulatory actions are
required by the CAA and EO 12866. In addition, each regulatory action is potentially subject
to a number of impact analyses required by both statutes and EOs. These analyses include an
analysis of impacts on State, local, and tribal governments under UMRA and EO 12875; an
analysis of impacts on small entities under RFA and SBREFA; an analysis of reporting and
recordkeeping requirements under the PRA and 5 CFR 1320; an analysis of the potential
impacts of a regulation on the health and safety of children; and an analysis of equity impacts,
particularly impacts on low-income and minority populations, under EO 12898.

2-16


-------
Section 3 — The Regulatory Development Process

SECTION 3

l lll REGULATORY DEVELOPMENT PROCESS

To place EIAs and EAs in context, this section discusses the broader processes by
which regulations are developed in EPA and OAQPS. The legal impetus for OAQPS
regulations and the analytical requirements for economic analysis are discussed in Section 2.
This section gives an overview of the regulatory development process at EPA in general and
OAQPS in particular, emphasizing the role of the economic analyses performed by ISEG in
this process. The section identifies benchmarks the ISEG analyst must adhere to along the
way.

The section begins with an overview of the EPA regulatory process. This discussion
is followed by a more detailed discussion of procedures within OAQPS and ISEG.

3.1 EPA Regulatory Development Process

EPA's regulatory development process (outlined in Figure 3-1) is designed to ensure
that all statutory and administrative requirements for rulemaking are met. The process is also
intended to allow for all EPA offices and regions with an interest in a rule to participate in
development of and to approve of that rule.1

The Agency's Regulatory Policy Council (RPC) is responsible for overseeing the
Agency's regulatory development process and ensuring that the process conforms with
Administration policy and addresses cross-cutting analytical issues. The RPC also monitors
the system to identify and implement any needed changes.

'For more detail on EPA's regulatory development process, see Browner, Carol M. Memorandum on Initiation
of EPA's Regulatory and Policy Development Process. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Office of
the Administrator. July 1, 1994.

3-1


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Figure 3-1. EPA Regulatory Development Process

3-2


-------
Section 3 — The Regulatory Development Process

The regulatory development process is initiated by the semi-annual submission of
anticipated regulatory actions for tiering assignment by senior Agency staff. Each regulatory
action is assigned one of three tiers:

•	Tier 1: Administrator's Priority Actions—Involves the few top actions that
demand ongoing involvement of the Administrator and extensive involvement of
Assistant Administrators (AAs) and Regional Administrators (RAs) across the
Agency.

•	Tier 2: Cross-Agency Actions—Actions have extensive cross-media effects,
requiring extensive cross-Agency involvement.

•	Tier 3: Lead-Office Delegation—Actions with little or no need for cross-Agency
participation.

This tiering process both prioritizes actions in terms of their potential for large and
multimedia effects and ensures early involvement of key Agency personnel. The formal
regulatory process outlined in Figure 3-1 and discussed below is required of all Tier 1 and
Tier 2 actions. Tier 3 actions are dealt with less formally but can involve many or all of the
procedural steps outlined here. While the tiering process imposes a hierarchy for Agency
actions, there is no direct relationship between the tiering process and the designation of
"significant regulatory actions" for OMB purposes (Browner, 1994).

3.1.1	Start A ction Notice

Once the regulatory action has been assigned a tier, a Start Action Notice (SAN) is
prepared by the lead AA/RA and is distributed to all AA and RA offices across the Agency.
This notice serves to solicit workgroup membership and other input from offices across the
Agency.

3.1.2	Workgroup Formation

After the SAN is approved by the RPC, the Agency workgroup is officially formed.
The Agency workgroup is an EPA-wide, staff-level group formed to develop a regulatory
action and supporting materials. The workgroup's primary responsibilities are to

•	identify and assess principal policy issues and options;

•	conduct technical and analytical work, including risk assessment work and
economic analysis;

3-3


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

•	resolve issues or elevate them for upper management resolution; and

•	ensure the quality and completeness of regulatory packages, including the Federal
Register (FR) notice.

Workgroup members are expected to represent the policy positions and perspectives of their
management as well as to contribute their technical and analytic expertise.

During the regulatory development process, one of the key responsibilities of each
workgroup member, including the economist, is to communicate key issues and results to
workgroup members and senior management. Without proper interpretation and
communication of results from the economic analysis, decisions might be made without
proper understanding of the rule's economic implications. For more discussion on methods
to communicate analytical results more effectively, see Section 9 of this document.

3.1.3	Early Guidance from Senior Management

Early involvement by senior management is one of the hallmark objectives of the
1994 reforms to the EPA regulatory development process. The purpose is to clarify, for the
workgroup, the objectives of the rulemaking and to identify the issues of significant concern
to senior management.

3.1.4	Analytical Blueprint

Consistent with the goal of having all regulatory actions be based on sound science,
an analytical blueprint is prepared to guide all forms of analysis throughout the
process—economic, scientific, legal, and institutional. The blueprint outlines the scope of
the action and requirements for analysis. The blueprint is considered a "living document" so
that the analysis plan can be modified if the situation warrants.

Once the blueprint is prepared, it is distributed to senior management across the
Agency for review and approval. The workgroup may need to revise the blueprint based on
cross-Agency review. The level and extent of review may differ slightly between Tier 1 and
Tier 2 actions.

3.1.5	Preliminary Analysis, Regulatory Options Development, and Selection of
Alternatives

In these stages, the workgroup analyzes and evaluates regulatory options to narrow
the scope of regulatory alternatives considered and then selects the regulatory alternative

3-4


-------
Section 3 — The Regulatory Development Process

from among the group of alternatives. This process is typically iterative, with the elimination
of some alternatives, possible addition of others, and ultimate selection of a final proposed
alternative. Senior management approval is an essential part of the iterative process. Senior
managers must accept that the options development process and final selection are based on
sound analysis of the alternatives.

The analysis/options development/selection process is the venue in which solid
economic (and other) analysis can make substantial contributions to the rulemaking process.
The lead economic analyst's responsibility is to ensure that the economic analyses are
technically strong and that the results of the analysis are communicated effectively to
workgroup members and senior management to help inform their decisions.

3.1.6 Rule Preparation and Workgroup Closure

Once the analyses have been performed and the regulatory alternative selected, the
workgroup must prepare the regulatory package for subsequent review and approval. The
regulatory package includes the FR notice for the proposed rule and all supporting
documentation.

The workgroup closure meeting occurs when the workgroup has prepared the
regulatory package and the management of the lead office has approved the notice and
analyses. The purpose of the workgroup closure meeting is to confirm that

•	the workgroup has successfully completed its job, resolving as many issues as
possible and clearly defining others;

•	the rulemaking package is ready for review at the AA, RA, and Deputy
Administrator levels; and

•	Agency and external requirements have been met.

Members of the workgroup participate in the workgroup closure meeting as
representatives of their AA/RA. Therefore, positions presented should be approved by the
respective AA/RA prior to the meeting. Although OAQPS workgroup members attend the
meeting, issues within OAQPS and Office of Air and Radiation (OAR) are not the focus of
the meeting, because these issues will have been addressed prior to the meeting as a condition
of package approval by the Office Director and the AA. Instead, the focus is on input
provided by the workgroup members from other EPA offices or regions.

3-5


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

3.1.7	OMB Review

The period for OMB review is 90 days for a proposed rule and 45 days for a final rule
if no material changes have been made since proposal; OMB can, however, extend this
period when it needs more time or when issues are unresolved. In virtually all cases, rules do
not go forward for final signature in EPA until the program office addresses OMB concerns
and resolves outstanding issues. Court-ordered deadlines and stringent statutory deadlines
may occasionally require that EPA publish a rule before OMB has finished its analysis and
comment or be given less time to review.2

Once workgroup closure has been attained and the package has been cleared for
submittal by the Administrator's office, the package is sent to OMB's Office of Information
and Regulatory Affairs (OIRA) for review. Under EO 12866, each proposed significant
regulatory action that the Agency issues must be sent to OMB for review before it is signed
by the Administrator. Again, the determination of significance for OMB purposes is not
directly related to EPA's tiering hierarchy. OIRA and the Agency will have determined in
advance whether a rule is deemed significant. The purpose of OMB review is to ensure that
the Agency's regulatory actions "are consistent with applicable law, the President's priorities,
and the principles set forth in [Executive Order 12866] and do not conflict with the policies
or actions of another agency" [EO 12866, Section 6(a)(4)],

Rules not considered significant can go straight to the Administrator for signature and
FR publication without OMB review.

3.1.8	Administrator's Signature and FR Publication of Proposed Rule

Recommended changes in the rule brought forth by OMB's review must generally be
addressed by the Agency before the rule can go forward. Once these issues are addressed, the
proposed rule is ready for the Administrator's signature. Once obtained, the signed rule is
forwarded to the Agency's FR liaison for final review and submission to the FR for
publication.

2See Section 2 of this guidance document for further discussion of E.O. 12866 and OMB review.

3-6


-------
Section 3 — The Regulatory Development Process

3.1.9	Public Comment, Rule Revision, and Signature and Publication of Proposed Rule

Publication of the proposed rule is followed by a public comment period, typically
lasting 60 days, in which any interested party has the opportunity to comment on the
proposed rule or the supporting analyses.

3.1.10	Rule Revision, Signature, and Publication of the Final Rule

After the public comment period closes, the workgroup is reconvened to review and
respond to the public comments and to prepare the final rule. The process for development
of the final rule is the same as for the proposed rule: analysis, senior management review,
workgroup closure, OMB review, Administrator's signature, and publication in the FR.

3.2 Economic Analysis in Regulatory Development

ISEG's primary role in the regulatory development process is to conduct the various
analyses categorized as economic and to report the results of the analyses to regulatory
decisionmakers. Each of those roles is described in more detail below.

3.2.1 Overview of Analysis Activity

Figure 3-2 presents an overview of the flow of analytical information in the regulatory
development process, with an emphasis on economic information. Because proposed
regulatory actions differ in scope, not all the activities presented in this figure may be
performed by ISEG for each regulation. However, this figure does reflect the primary
components of an economic analysis and illustrates the basic relationships between input
data, analysis, and results. The majority of the ISEG analysts' efforts are focused on
developing the industry profile, the economic impact analysis, and the benefits analysis.3
These activities are summarized below.

Industry profiles provide detailed information on the affected industry, entities, and
markets. Data are typically obtained from a combination of sources, including information
gathered by EPA and summarized in previous regulatory support documents; data from
publicly available sources; and data from stakeholders. The information is used to identify
affected commodities; characterize baseline conditions in affected markets, including prices

3The "economic analysis," when prepared for major rules, is essentially a compilation of all relevant analytical
results described here and does not involve additional substantive analytical work.

3-7


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Economic Information
Used in Regulatory
Decisionmaking

Figure 3-2. Flow of Analytical Information in Regulatory Development

3-8


-------
Section 3 — The Regulatory Development Process

and quantities, market structure, and international trade; identify and locate producers and
consumers of affected commodities; identify and characterize the firms owning the affected
facilities; and characterize baseline conditions in the communities where affected producers
are located (the populations who will affected by the regulation). Section 4 provides details
on the development of these industry profiles.

Economic impact analysis involves estimating the reallocation of society's resources
and the social costs associated with the proposed regulatory action. The industry profile
provides the baseline characterization of market conditions from which the impacts of the
regulation are estimated. Frequently an analysis involves developing an analytical approach
and computer model to simulate the behavioral responses of the affected entities to the
regulation in a market context. The approach is designed to be consistent with economic
theory and to produce integrated estimates of the responses of affected facilities, firms, and
markets. Also included are impact estimates for selected location and company size
categories to support impact analysis for small entities and minority and low-income
populations. The analyst should refer to EPA (1997e) for more detailed discussion of the
engineering inputs to the economic analysis. Section 5 provides details on the development
of EIAs for ISEG, while Section 6 provides specifics on the supplemental impact analyses
that are required by EO or statute.

Benefits analysis involves analyzing all the categories of benefits by first identifying
then quantifying and, where possible, monetizing the benefits. The benefits of pollution
controls are defined as the increases in human welfare that result from improvements in
environmental quality. Assessing the benefits of air pollution controls requires a conceptual
framework that specifically links reductions in air pollutant emissions to human welfare
enhancements. Such a framework distinguishes the essential components of benefits and
ensures that all relevant benefits are accounted for and not double counted. Section 7
provides details on the development of benefits analyses for ISEG.

3.2.2 A Note on Cost/Control Strategy Analysis for NAAQS

Economic analyses performed in ISEG often address industry or source-specific
control strategies (e.g., MACT standards). In those cases, compliance strategies and their
costs are fairly well-defined in the engineering analysis prior to economic analysis. However,
the setting is different for the analysis of national ambient air quality standards (NAAQS), in
which case compliance strategies and associated costs are not necessarily well-defined prior

3-9


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

to economic analysis. Important features of cost analysis unique to NAAQS rulemakings are
highlighted here.

Under CAA section 110, EPA sets NAAQS for criteria pollutants. The CAA does not
authorize the Agency to consider the cost of achieving a NAAQS in establishing the level of
the standard; however, since most new or revised NAAQS met the definition of "significant"
actions defined in Executive Order 12866, a NAAQS rulemaking package must be
accompanied by an assessment of the potential cost and benefits of the standard. Unlike
other federal rules that specify both the sources that must control, and the technologies or
specific emission limits that must be met, NAAQS only establish an ambient air quality goal.
Under the CAA, state and local governments (hereafter, states) and their designated air
quality departments are responsible for developing the specific pollution control strategies
that will enable an area designated out of attainment with a NAAQS to met the ambient air
quality goal.

A benefit-cost assessment is more uncertain in this context because the specific
pollution control strategies that states will use to attain the standard are not necessarily
known. To simulate the possible costs and benefits associated with a new or revised
NAAQS, EPA may construct one or more hypothetical implementation scenarios. In these
scenarios, EPA attempts to model the potential control measures of other control strategies
that states might adopt to meet the standard. For some NAAQS, only a few select areas of
the country may not meet the standard, which indicates that smaller scale analyses are
appropriate. However, for other NAAQS, many areas of the country may not meet the
standard, which calls for an essentially nationwide analysis. In either case, EPA collects data
on the emissions sources believed to be contributing to the air pollution problem, and
develops control measures to estimate the costs and emissions reductions that can potentially
be achieved.

Some larger sources are identified individually as "point" sources, while other smaller
sources are identified collectively as "area" sources. For point sources, EPA may be able to
collect enough source-specific information to develop reasonable study estimates (±30%
accuracy) of the cost and emission reductions attributable to a particular control device or
control measure. In these cases, total annual compliance costs are generated at the source
level similar to the way compliance costs are generated for other source-specific regulations.
For area sources, where source-specific information is sparse or nonexistent, EPA may
develop more generic "cost-effectiveness" estimates, where total annual compliance costs for

3-10


-------
Section 3 — The Regulatory Development Process

a group of sources is generated by multiplying the cost-effectiveness value by the annual
emission reduction that is expected from the source group. In these cases, the cost borne by
any one source in the group is less certain.

3.2.3 Structure and Content of ISEG Reports

Although the ISEG analyst is responsible for all written technical support documents
related to the economic analysis, the majority of time and effort will be spent preparing the
industry profile and the EIA (EA) report. The structure and content of these reports are
summarized below.

The industry profile report will typically include the following sections:

•	Introduction. This section provides an overview of the regulated industry and the
organization of the industry profile report.

•	Supply. This section details the affected production processes, inputs, associated
final products and residuals, and the costs of production.

•	Demand. This section details the characteristics, uses, consumers of the affected
commodities, and the substitution possibilities.

•	Industry organization. This section discusses the market structure of the affected
industry and provides detailed information on the manufacturing facilities and
owning companies.

•	Markets. This section provides historical and projected data on U.S. production,
foreign trade, consumption, and market prices.

This profile is often included in the public docket with a summary version also included in
the EIA (EA) report.

The technical support document that reports the methods and results of the economic
analysis will differ in structure and content between nonsignificant and significant regulatory
actions. For nonsignificant regulatory actions, the executive and legislative requirements are
less demanding, so the EIA report will typically include the following sections:

•	Executive summary. This section provides an overview of the regulated industry;
the proposed regulatory alternatives and costs; the data, methodology, and
assumptions of the economic analysis; and the economic impact results.

3-11


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

•	Introduction. This section summarizes the scope and purpose, statutory authority,
and the organization of the EIA report.

•	Industry profile. This section provides a summary profile extracted from the
industry profile report developed prior to the economic analysis.

•	Compliance cost analysis. This section reviews the proposed regulatory
alternatives and associated costs of compliance.

•	Economic impact analysis. This section provides a summary of the analysis
inputs and economic methodology for assessing the economic impacts of the
proposed regulation and the analysis results, including the impacts on markets,
facilities, and industry as well as the social costs.

•	Impacts analysis. This section includes methods and results for the supplemental
impact analyses as required by EO and statute. For an EIA, this section usually
only includes an assessment of the impact on small entities (businesses,
governments, organizations).

Alternatively, the report supporting a full EA for significant regulatory actions must meet
additional executive and legislative requirements and should include the following:

•	Executive summary. This section provides an overview of the regulated industry;
the proposed regulatory alternatives and costs; the data, methodology, and
assumptions of the economic impact and benefits analyses; and the economic
impact and benefits results.

•	Introduction. This section summarizes the scope and purpose, statutory authority,
and the organization of the EA report.

•	Industry profile. This section provides a summary profile extracted from the
industry profile report developed prior to the economic analysis.

•	Needfor regulation. This section summarizes the market conditions that
necessitate regulatory action, the harmful effects of the air emissions, and the
consequences of regulation.

•	Compliance cost analysis. This section reviews the proposed regulatory
alternatives and associated costs of compliance.

•	Economic impact analysis. This section provides a summary of the analysis
inputs and economic methodology for assessing the economic impacts of the
proposed regulation and the analysis results, including the impacts on markets,
facilities, and industry as well as the social costs.

3-12


-------
Section 3 — The Regulatory Development Process

•	Impacts analysis. This section includes methods and results for the supplemental
impact analyses as required by EO and statute. For an EA report, this section may
contain all of the required analyses, including impacts on small entities; minority
or low-income populations; and state, local, or tribal governments and reporting
and recordkeeping requirements.

•	Benefits analysis. This section describes the analysis inputs and methods used for
estimating and valuing the effect of reduced environmental and human exposure
to air emissions.

•	Benefit-cost comparison. This section provides a comparison of the social
benefits and costs of the proposed regulatory action.

In addition, the EIA (EA) report should include technical appendices that provide the details
on input data, assumptions, methods, and sensitivity results that may be of use to certain
interested parties.

3.3 Specific ISEG Tasks in the Regulatory Development Process

Section 3.1 outlines the regulatory development process that is broadly applicable
across program offices at EPA and Section 3.2 highlights the role of economic analysis in the
process. This section deals specifically with the economic analysis tasks that take place in
ISEG throughout the process. The main activities within ISEG are categorized in Figure 3-3
and reviewed briefly below.

3.3.1 Initial Screening

The purpose of the initial screening stage is to assess the likely magnitude of impacts
of the proposed regulatory actions. This stage allows ISEG to prioritize its activities and
thereby use its analytical resources more efficiently. At this point, ISEG must determine
which of the analysis categories the proposed regulatory action falls into:

•	minimal

•	active (EIA)

•	major (EA)

Those actions falling into the "minimal" category are rules that are expected to have very
small impacts and thereby require relatively little formal analysis. "Active" projects are
expected to have large enough impacts to warrant a full EIA, but not large enough to warrant

3-13


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Figure 3-3. Main Activities Within ISEG in the Regulatory Development Process

a full EA. The "major" rules are those that are deemed significant regulatory actions under
EO 12866 (see Section 2) and thereby require substantial analytical resources to perform a
full analysis of benefits, costs, and other socio-economic impacts. Most of the OAQPS
regulatory actions fall in the minimal and active categories (MACT standards, NSPS), with
relatively few designated as major (NAAQS, some MACT standards).

3.3.2 Scoping Assessment and SBREFA Determination

In this stage, active and major projects are further scrutinized to determine the scope
of analyses that need to be performed and the corresponding level of effort. This may involve
reviewing information on the regulated industry or activity; the type of pollution control
alternatives being considered; the expected effect on environmental quality; and the
availability of data and models to estimate costs, benefits, and distributional effects. Often
this information is generated by other groups within OAQPS as part of the Office's activity

3-14


-------
Section 3 — The Regulatory Development Process

prior to economic analysis. This information may need to be supplemented with additional
secondary data.

This is also the point in the process where the Agency must determine whether the
proposed rule is likely to have a significant impact on a substantial number of small entities,
a threshold criterion established by SBREFA. Upon completion of the SBREFA screening
analysis, the Agency must either certify that there will not be a significant impact on a
substantial number of small entities or convene a SBREFA review panel to participate in the
rulemaking process. See Sections 2 and 6 for more information on the regulatory background
of SBREFA and the analytical methods for addressing SBREFA impacts.

3.3.3	Industry Profile

The industry profile stage is often the first intensive activity in the economic analysis
process. The purpose of the industry profile is threefold:

•	characterize the economic characteristics of the regulated industry that are
important for understanding the potential benefits and costs of the proposed
regulatory action,

•	set the analytical context for the EIA/EA, and

•	collect data for subsequent analysis.

The profile should provide detail on the relevant economic characteristics of the regulated
industry in question and should compile the data necessary to define a baseline for the
analysis and to estimate model parameters. The profile may draw from information provided
earlier in the regulatory process within OAQPS. The purpose, structure, and data
requirements of industry profiles are discussed in more detail in Section 4 of this document.

3.3.4	A nalysis Plan

The preliminary scoping assessment described above should paint a broad picture of
issues to be addressed in the economic analysis. Since this preliminary assessment, time has
passed and allows for engineering information on the compliance costs and regulatory
alternatives to influence the scope and scale of the economic analysis. Supplemented with
the data and other economic information gathered in the industry profile, the next task is to
prepare a detailed methodology for performing the analysis. This is part of the analytical
blueprint stage referenced above.

3-15


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

The methodology for performing an EIA should specify how costs and economic
impacts will be estimated and reported. Section 5 of this document presents an analytical
framework for modeling costs and economic impacts, taking into consideration the economic
responses of producers and consumers in the affected markets. The methods outlined in that
section work toward providing estimates of costs and distributional impacts that are both
consistent with economic theory and address the analytical requirements posed by the various
statutory and administrative requirements presented in Section 2.

The analysis plan for performing a full EA for significant regulatory actions ("major"
rules) should supplement the EIA methodology with a methodology for estimating the
benefits of the regulatory action. An analytical framework for benefits estimation methods is
presented in Section 7 of this document.

3.3.5 Analysis

In this stage, the methodology and data are combined to perform the analysis.

Analysis tasks include

•	model development,

•	testing,

•	preliminary analysis of regulatory alternatives,

•	evaluation and external review, and

•	final analysis of regulatory alternatives.

The analytical models will depend on the scope of the analysis to be performed. Potential
model types include compliance cost estimation models, partial or general equilibrium
models of the regulated markets, financial impact models, and benefits estimation models
(e.g., health effects models, cost-of-illness models, valuation models, and benefits transfer).

Model testing is an essential component of quality assurance/quality control (QA/QC)
procedures. Testing is absolutely necessary to ensure confidence in the model results on the
part of the analyst, workgroup members, Agency management, stakeholders, and the general
public. Testing and QA/QC, along with the peer-review process are integral parts of the
Agency's policy for using sound science to support regulatory decisions.

3-16


-------
Section 3 — The Regulatory Development Process

As indicated in Section 3.1, analysis is usually an iterative process within the
Agency's regulatory development process. Preliminary analysis results can be used by the
workgroup to define and select regulatory alternatives. Or regulatory alternatives may change
for reasons unrelated to the preliminary analyses, such as statutory factors, stakeholder input,
or changes in data or analytical inputs. Ultimately, though, a final analysis will be performed
on the selected regulatory option, and the analysis results will be used to support the
regulatory decision in the OMB review and public comment periods.

3.3.6 Technical Support Documents

The CAA and EO 12866 both require that all analysis results relevant to the
regulatory decision be documented in writing. Of primary importance to ISEG are the
following written documents:

•	the EIA (EA) report

•	preamble to the FR notice

•	public docket

The EIA (EA) report summarizes the data, methods, assumptions, and results used to analyze
the regulatory actions under consideration. The report should be substantive, in the sense that
the reader should have all of the information necessary to understand how the results were
derived and what they imply. However, the report should avoid needless detail that will
hamper its readability. The preamble states the need for regulatory action and summarizes
the analytical results that support the proposed action. The docket includes all materials
referenced in the analysis. Its function is to allow any interested parties access to all
information used to support the regulatory decision.

3-17


-------
Section 4 — Industry Profile Development

SECTION 4
INDUSTRY PROFILE DEVELOPMENT

This section summarizes the development of the industry profile, which provides the
foundation for the development of the economic analysis. The profile provides details on the
relevant economic and financial characteristics and trends for the industry in question as well
as a compilation of the data necessary to define a baseline for the analysis and estimate
required parameters for the economic model. It is the responsibility of the economic analyst
to supplement industry data generated in earlier stages of the regulatory process with available
primary and secondary sources to complete the industry profile as described below.

4.1 Purpose and Use

As mentioned above, the industry profile provides the foundation for the development
of the economic analysis. For a particular industry, or group of industries, the major purposes
of the profile include the following:

1.	to assemble, describe, and present all relevant financial and economic
characteristics and trends—past, present, and future;

2.	to provide an understanding of the industry organization, including market
structure and the conduct and performance of affected firms;

3.	to identify the key factors and trends that may influence the nature and magnitude
of the economic impacts and that may be addressed in the economic analysis (e.g.,
significance of international trade); and

4.	to provide information necessary to identify and characterize special populations in
accordance with legislative and administrative directives (e.g., small businesses
under SBREFA; state, local, and tribal governments under UMRA; and minority
and low-income groups under E.O. 12898 on environmental justice).

The economic analyst uses the information provided in the industry profile in the following
ways:

4-1


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

1.	as the basis for determining the level of analysis to be performed and justifying the
assumptions to be used in the economic analysis,

2.	to provide the statistical and analytical basis for the selected methodological
framework in defining the baseline for the economic analysis and/or estimating
model parameters, and

3.	to assess the feasibility of and provide the data necessary for calculating the impact
of a regulation on special populations.

As described below, the market orientation of the methodological framework for economic
analysis conducted by ISEG has determined the structure and content of the industry profile.

4.2 Structure and Content

Table 4-1 provides an annotated industry profile outline that should serve as the basis
for developing an industry profile. The proposed structure and content should be considered
a flexible framework for initial development of the profile that should be subsequently tailored
to fit the specifics of the subject industry. The profile structure shown in Table 4-1 has been
used for numerous industry profiles in ISEG, and the profile content has facilitated the
development of many economic analyses of proposed regulatory actions. In addition, the
industry profile conveys EPA's understanding of the potentially affected industry to other
interested parties involved in the regulatory development process. This allows industry
representatives and others to review and provide comments on the accuracy and
appropriateness of the information that will serve as the basis for the economic analysis.

Because of time and resource constraints, in some cases, some of the industry profile
data elements outlined in Table 4-1 cannot be obtained. When data are not readily available,
the specific needs of the economic analysis should determine the choices made about selective
data collection. In these cases, the EPA WAM should determine which data are essential for
the completion of a satisfactory economic analysis. This decision will vary from case to case,
so there is no unique list of minimum data requirements. However, data that would be
considered indispensable in conducting a market analysis would include baseline market
volumes and prices, assumed or estimated supply and demand price elasticities, and company-
level sales and employment data to address impacts on small businesses.

4-2


-------
Section 4 — Industry Profile Development

Table 4-1. Annotated Industry Profile Outline

Section	Description

1	Introduction

(Brief description of the source category, current economic condition and trends,
and the environmental concerns. Overview of organization of profile.)

2	The Supply Side

2.1	Production Process

(Describe production process to characterize inputs and final
commodities that are to be the focus of the economic analysis and assist
in identifying the appropriate economic representation of the production
process, i.e., production functions and cost functions. Discuss joint
production of commodities, input substitution possibilities, and final
product substitution possibilities at the facility. Also, address input ratios
and economies of scale and scope.)

2.2	Major By-Products and Co-products

(Identify unregulated commodities resulting from the above production
processes that are important in determining viability of the facility, i.e.
valuable by-products that contribute to revenues. These commodities
may be indirectly affected by the regulation and therefore should be
included in the analysis or at least qualitatively identified.)

2.3	Types of Products/Services

(Identify the various products resulting from the production process,
which also contributes to identifying affected and unaffected products.)

2.4	Costs of Production

(Identify major cost components to assist in projecting baseline costs of
production and determining shape or form of marginal cost or average
cost functions.)

2.4.1	Capital Costs

2.4.2	Raw Material Costs

2.4.3	Labor Costs

2.4.4	Energy Costs

2.4.5	Other Costs

(continued)

4-3


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Table 4-1. Annotated Industry Profile Outline (Continued)

Section	Description

3	The Demand Side

3.1	Product Characteristics

(Describe the product attributes that are desired by consumers.)

3.2	Uses and Consumers

(Identify major uses and consumers of the products, which contributes to
our characterization of demand, e.g., derived demand versus final product
demand. Also, provide own-price demand elasticities from literature or
estimates.)

3.3	Substitution Possibilities in Consumption

(Discuss other products that are possible substitutes to consumers and
provide any empirical data on elasticities of demand by use or consumer.)

4	Industry Organization

4.1	Market Structure

(Define the products and producers that constitute the "market." Discuss
market shares and behavior of consumers and producers, i.e.,
monopolistic, oligopolistic, or perfectly competitive markets. Base
discussion on existing literature on these markets and industries.)

4.2	Manufacturing Plants

(Provide this detailed information to assist in incorporating these facilities
into the economic model. Manufacturing plants form the basis of the
economic model whether explicitly incorporated or not.)

4.2.1

Location

4.2.2

Age

4.2.3

Production Capacity and Utilization

4.2.4

Employment

4.2.5

Trends



4.2.5.1 Plants and Capacity



4.2.5.2 Technologies

(continued)

4-4


-------
Section 4 — Industry Profile Development

Table 4-1. Annotated Industry Profile Outline (Continued)

Section	Description

4.3 Firm Characteristics

(Characterize the potentially affected business entities that own the
regulated facilities. This characterization includes legal form of
ownership and issues of integration that influence how firms are affected
by regulation, and firm size that contributes to conducting a regulatory
flexibility analysis.)

4.3.1	Ownership

4.3.2	Size Distribution

4.3.3	Vertical and Horizontal Integration

4.3.4	Financial Condition

5	Markets

(Provide historical and projected data on domestic production and consumption
of relevant products, as well as international trade data. Influences the selection
of a base year of analysis and informs about importance of including international
trade in the economic analysis.)

5.1	Market Volumes

5.1.1	Domestic Production

5.1.2	Domestic Consumption

5.1.3	Internati onal Trade

5.2	Market Prices

5.3	Future Proj ections

5.3.1	Domestic Production

5.3.2	Domestic Consumption

5.3.3	International Trade

5.3.4	Market Prices

6	References

4-5


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

4.3 Data Sources

This section provides a summary and evaluation of the data sources used in developing
industry profiles. In preparing these industry profiles, the economic analyst will gather
information from a wide variety of sources. For source-specific regulations, the source
category subject to the proposed regulation is typically identified by a standard industry code,
formerly the Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) code, now the North American Industry
Classification System (NAICS). This identification will determine the primary sources of
information to be used for the profile (e.g., major trade associations and government
agencies). For source-specific regulations, the starting point may be the survey responses by
sources within the subject industry to EPA's ICR or Section 114 letters. In those cases, the
ISEG analyst should obtain a copy of the survey instrument to determine the information that
can be expected from these responses. The types of information usually provided for each
source category include the following:

•	identification and location of potentially affected manufacturing plants,

•	identification of parent company owner of each plant,

•	industrial processes and input usage at each plant,

•	Industry codes and/or final product descriptions (i.e., type of product and/or end
use),

•	individual plant capacity (or process/equipment capacities), and

•	age of manufacturing plant and/or equipment.

The analyst should review the data for accuracy and adequacy and report any major questions,
data gaps, or other deficiencies to the work group to address possible shortcomings at the
early stage of profile development. The economic analyst should then supplement these
survey data with available primary and secondary sources to complete the industry profile.

To facilitate an understanding of subject industries and to identify data sources, EPA's
Office of Enforcement and Compliance Assurance (OECA) has developed a series of profiles
containing information on selected major industrial groups. These industry profiles, or
Industry Sector Notebooks, provide useful summary information on industrial processes and
input usage, final product characterization, industry organization, general economic trends,
and existing regulatory requirements. These documents also provide an extensive list of

4-6


-------
Section 4 — Industry Profile Development

bibliographic references that can assist economic analysts in their initial literature search and
data collection efforts. Industry Sector Notebooks range in length from 84 to 180 pages and
are currently available for those industries listed in Table 4-2. OECA is also planning to add
profiles on the following industries in the near future:

•	aerospace,

•	agricultural chemicals,

•	agricultural crop production,

•	agricultural stock production,

•	coal mining, and

•	oil and gas exploration and production.

These Notebooks are available for downloading from EPA's web site  in one or more electronic file formats including HTML, Adobe
Acrobat (PDF), WordPerfect for Macintosh 3.0/DOS 5.1/Windows 6.1, and Word for
Macintosh 5.1a.

Primary sources of information for industry profiles will be industry trade associations
and government agencies. Major trade associations related to the subject industry can be
identified through the Industry Sector Notebooks, through discussions with the engineers, or
through Internet searches. Additional sources for identifying trade associations include the
Encyclopedia of Associations published by Gale Research Company and National Trade and
Professional Associations of the United States published by Columbia Books, Inc. Major
government sources of information include the U.S. Department of Commerce's Bureau of
Census, the U.S. Department of Energy's Energy Information Administration and Office of
Industrial Technologies, and the U.S. International Trade Commission. In particular, useful
industry overviews and general data are provided by the U.S. International Trade
Commission's Industry and Trade Summaries (individual reports for selected industries) and
the U.S. Department of Commerce's U.S. Industry and Trade Outlook (single report covering
all industries across U.S. economy, formerly the U.S. Industrial Outlook)1

'Tables from the U.S. Industry and Trade Outlook by industry sector are available online at
.

4-7


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Table 4-2. List of Industries with EPA Sector Notebooks

Industry Description

SIC Code(s)(a)

Air Transportation Industry

SIC 45

Dry Cleaning Industry

SIC 721

Electronics and Computer Industry

SIC 36

Fossil Fuel Electric Power Generation Industry

SIC 4911, 493

Ground Transportation Industry—Railroad, Trucking,
and Pipeline

SIC 40, 42, 46, and 49

Inorganic Chemical Industry

SIC 281

Iron and Steel Industry

SIC 331

Lumber and Wood Products Industry

SIC 24

Metal Casting Industry

SIC 332, 336

Metal Fabrication Industry

SIC 34

Metal Mining Industry

SIC 10

Motor Vehicle Assembly Industry

SIC 37

Nonferrous Metals Industry

Part of SIC 33

Non-Fuel, Non-Metal Mining Industry

SIC 14

Organic Chemical Industry

SIC 286

Petroleum Refining Industry

SIC 2911

Pharmaceutical Industry

SIC 2833, 2834

Plastics Resins and Man-made Fibers Industry

SIC 2821, 2823, 2824

Printing Industry

SIC 27

Pulp and Paper Industry

SIC 26

Rubber and Plastic Industry

SIC 30

Shipbuilding and Repair Industry

SIC 3731

Stone, Clay, Glass, and Concrete Industry

SIC 32

Textiles Industry

SIC 22

Transportation Equipment Industry

SIC 2911, 3743, 3795, 3799, 4491, and others

Water Transportation Industry

SIC 44

Wood Furniture and Fixtures Industry

SIC 2511, 2512, 2517, 2519, 2521, 2531, 2541

(a) The Sector Notebooks were developed subject to the old SIC code referencing system. See the web page
 to cross-reference from the old SIC system to the new North
American Industry Classification System (NAICS).

4-8


-------
Section 4 — Industry Profile Development

The analyst, of course, should always conduct a detailed literature search through
academic, research, or government libraries for books and articles related to the subject
industry. These searches can now be performed online through the Internet. For example, the
North Carolina State University libraries can be accessed through the Internet at
, while other academic and research libraries with web
servers can be identified and accessed through Libweb at

. Furthermore, other general sources for industry
overviews and statistics include the following:

•	Gale Research Company publications such as Encyclopedia of American
Industries, U.S. Industry Profiles: The Leading 100, and Manufacturing U.S.A.;

•	private consulting firm studies available online through information service
providers (e.g., Profound, DIALOG) or directly from the consulting firm's web
site (e.g., The Freedonia Group, SRI International);

•	investor research reports published by Standard and Poor's, Moody's, and Value-
Line Investments; and

•	Chemical Economics Handbook (CEH), SRI International. The CEH is a
comprehensive multi-volume study of the chemical industry consisting of hundreds
of reports on major segments of the industry and on individual chemicals or related
groups of chemicals. Each report in CEH is periodically updated and the reports
range in age from 6 months to 6 or 7 years, with 2 or 3 years being average.

In addition, several web sites provide access to industry information and resources such as
The Chemical Industry Home Page at  (industry-specific source) or
Yahoo! Finance at  (general source across many industries). The
specific sources typically used for each section of the profile outline presented in Table 4-1 are
summarized below.

4.3.1 The Supply Side

This section of the profile provides information about the supply side of the affected
industry, focusing on identification and characterization of the affected production processes,
the resulting final and residual products, and the costs of production. Table 4-3 provides
several resources that have been identified as providing useful information for this section of
the profile. A discussion of these sources and the relevant information they are likely to
provide is presented below.

4-9


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

In the engineering analysis stage of the regulatory process (see Figure 3-2), EPA
identifies and characterizes affected production processes and, sometimes, the resulting
products and residuals. Typically, the economic analyst must consult other sources to provide
this information or to supplement the information provided by the engineering analysis.
Additional primary sources for this type of information include the following:

•	EPA Sector Notebooks. This government source provides very good summaries of
the technologies, processes, and products for selected industries (current list
shown in Table 4-2). These summaries include useful diagrams of the production
flows as well as illustrations of specific equipment or processes.

•	Trade Associations. Trade associations often publish brochures or summary
reports that provide information on technologies, processes, and products. Many
of these associations have World Wide Web sites that provide online reference
materials, publications lists, and links to other data sources.

•	Company Web Sites. Companies often provide general descriptions and diagrams
of their production technologies and processes, as well as information on the
resulting final and residual products (i.e., saleable or recyclable products and
pollutants).

As shown, other sources include previous EPA investigations (i.e., profiles or economic
analyses), textbooks and technical manuscripts published by industry or academic experts,

Gale Research Company's How Products are Made, and industry or specialty reference
materials such as the Kirk-Othmer and the Ullmann's chemical-related encyclopedias. The
Ullmann 's Encyclopedia of Industrial Chemistry contains 36 volumes with more than
800 major articles and over 26,000 pages of information in industrial chemistry, process
engineering, materials science, environmental chemistry, food science, and biotechnology.2

Information on production costs for affected entities can also be provided through
EPA's engineering analysis. However, most often, the economic analyst is required to consult
other sources for this information. For source-specific regulations, general information on
production costs for the subject industry can be obtained from trade association publications
or economic or technical research literature. For example, some trade journals have annual
survey articles that summarize these costs (i.e., Rock Products for cement operations), or
some researchers have already estimated these costs or the relevant functional relationships.

2The recently released 6th edition is available in electronic format, see the Ullmann home page at
 for more details.

4-10


-------
Section 4 — Industry Profile Development

si



"§

Ph

K»%


o

bfi

X>
£
£
£

43

V

ss

ia
o

A
>
o

bC

o

bC
tA
bC

a a

2 2

V V

ss

O

"S

C3

S3 S3
'G 'G
Ph Ph

S3
o

o

0



a

5

O

C/5

#

"3

CO

^3

s:

Q

Co

Co
O

s:

¦2

o
s<

aj a

u -3
a -5

5< Co

<0

R

r a

a ^

#1

R ^

~5 &H

»>%

O

0

1

o

c3

•g

§

'5b	"5

r-	d)

S	CO

c	<

CLh	CLh

W	W

e
o

cd
bD

%

•g



%

-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

In addition, the Industry and Trade Summaries reports published by the U.S. International
Trade Commission often provide industry survey data on the production costs of the subject
industry. Sources that can provide costs of specific factors of production include the
following:

•	BLS LAB STAT Database (labor),

•	Energy Information Administration (energy and power),

•	U.S. Geological Survey (raw materials), and

•	Synthetic Organic Chemicals and Chemical Marketing Reporter (chemicals).

The factor-specific cost data obtained from these and other sources can be used to generate
estimates of the production costs, given specification of the appropriate production or cost
function.

4.3.2 The Demand Side

This section of the profile provides information about the demand side of the affected
industry focusing on identification and characterization of the attributes of the affected
product(s), consumers and end uses, and the substitution possibilities in consumption.3
Table 4-4 provides several resources that have been identified as providing such information.
Typically, the economic analyst must consult other sources to provide this information or to
supplement the information provided by the engineering analysis. Furthermore, the U.S.
ITC's Industry and Trade Summary reports provide very good summary information to
identify and characterize consumers and end uses, as well as substitutes. Additional primary
sources for this type of information include the following:

•	Trade Associations. Trade associations often publish brochures detailing product
characteristics and comparisons with substitutes, as well as statistic reports that
provide historical and projected data on end-use market shares and volumes

3This section may also include specification of the elasticity of demand, which measures the responsiveness of
quantity demanded to price changes. The demand elasticity is a necessary parameter in the market-based
approach to conducting EIAs (as described fully in Section 5). Values for this key parameter can be
obtained from previous academic or EPA analyses of the subject industry or can be estimated using
econometric techniques as discussed in previous EIA reports (see Research Triangle Institute, 1998). If
parameter estimates are not available or feasible to estimate, then the analyst may rely on other means to
determine whether an elastic or inelastic characterization would be most appropriate for the economic
analysis.

4-12


-------
Section 4 — Industry Profile Development

consumed. Many of these associations have World Wide Web sites that provide
on-line reference materials, publications lists, and links to other sources of data.

•	Company Web Sites. Companies often provide general descriptions of their
products as well as useful comparisons of their product lines with competitors'
products or other general substitute products.

•	U.S. Bureau of Census. This government sources provide publications and data
on U.S. economic activity and specific industries as identified formerly by SIC
codes and currently by NAICS codes. For historical data on end-use volumes, the
Current Industrial Report is a very good source for selected industries and
products (available online at .

•	U.S. Geological Survey. This government source provides publications and data
on the U.S. and global supply, demand, and flow of minerals and materials. For
some minerals and materials, the information provides an identification of end uses
and the historical volumes consumed by each end use (available online at
).

•	Private Consulting Firm Studies. These studies may be a good source of detailing
product characteristics, identifying substitutes, and providing historical and
projected data on end-use market shares and volumes consumed. However, the
analyst should be aware that the data provided in these sources may be
compilations of publicly available information, and the methodology or
assumptions for projections are typically not provided in sufficient detail.

As shown, other sources of this type of information include previous EPA investigations (i.e.,
profiles or economic analyses), textbooks and technical manuscripts published by industry or
academic experts, and industry or specialty reference materials such as Kirk-Othmer and
Ullmann's encyclopedias.

4.3.3 Industry Organization

This section of the profile characterizes the structure of the subject markets, the plants
that manufacture the affected products, and the firms that own these manufacturing plants.

4.3.3.1 Market Structure

Market structure is important to understanding an industry because it determines the
behavior of producers and consumers in the industry. To assess the competitiveness of a
market, economists often estimate four-firm concentration ratios (CR4) and Herfindahl-
Hirschman indexes (HHI) for the subject market or industry. These measures of market

4-13


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

.a
—
"3



•>% !>%

| |

"H "H "H
•c *c *c

Oh Oh Oh


o

bX)

C	bX)



a

5

O

a
•c

-s

£
C/3

ts

o

Qh

r>	^

S	O

5	o

6	£
O	0)

U	H

u

t+H

o

.2	o

"S	.2

Qh	T3

O	



o
Q
s<
Q

8

^3

s:
Q

§

^3

o

j

> -5

•s

C/)

t5
o

Qh



§


-------
Section 4 — Industry Profile Development

concentration are provided by four-digit SIC codes in the U.S. Bureau of the Census
publication Concentration Ratios in Manufacturing. An additional source of seller
concentration measures is the Market Share Reporter, published by Gale Research Company,
which annually compiles market share data on companies, products, and services. However,
additional information must be obtained and evaluated in the industry profile because no
objective criteria exist for determining market structure based on these concentration
measures. Thus, the economic analyst should consult the economic and industry literature to
inform the selection or characterization of markets.4

4.3.3.2 Manufacturing Plants

Although sources providing information at the facility level are limited, Table 4-5
provides several resources identified as providing such information. A discussion of these
sources and the relevant information they are likely to provide is presented below.

Trade Associations. Trade associations often publish directories that list individual
facility characteristics and other valuable information. Many of these associations have World
Wide Web sites that provide publications lists, industry statistics, and links to other sources of
data. For example, the American Portland Cement Association maintains a web site at
 with useful general and economic information on this industry
in addition to publishing an annual plant information summary that provides detailed data on
location, technology, capacity, and company ownership information of manufacturing plants.

Industry Buyers' Guides. Many industries publish buyers' guides that list facility
location information as well as product information. For example, the Chemical Marketing
Reporter publishes the Chemical Buyers Directory that lists supplier and product information,
while Chemical Week and Vertical Net, Inc. provide similar information through online guides
(i.e., Buyers' Guide at  and Chemical Online at
). In addition, MacRAE'S Blue Book is a
comprehensive national buying guide of 50,000 prominent U.S. manufacturers including their
products and trade names. This source is available in print and online through a fee-based
subscription service at .

4See the pharmaceuticals (Research Triangle Institute, 1996b) or portland cement (Research Triangle Institute,
1996a) industry profiles for more detailed description of this issue.

4-15


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Table 4-5. Data Elements for Facility-Specific Sources

Legal	Process/Product	Product

Data Source

Owner

Location

Descriptions

Capacity

Revenues

Employment

Industry Trade
Associations

X

X

X

X





Industry Buyers'
Guides

X

X

X







U.S. SEC/EDGAR
Database®

X

X

X

X

X

X

Company Web Sites

X

X

X

X





Dun & Bradstreet
Market Identifiers11

X

X





X

X

American Business
Disk



X





X

X

U.S. Manufacturers
Database0

X

X

X



X

X

a Non-subscription service with web access via .
b Electronic database available through EPA's Facility Index System (FINDS).
c Fee-based subscription service with web access via .

U.S. Security and Exchange Commission. EDGAR Database. This source consists of
electronic filings by public corporations to the Securities and Exchange Commission (i.e.,
10-K reports) and is available through the Internet at .
Some companies publish detailed information on their manufacturing operations as well as
markets served. However, this information may often times only include plant location.

Corporate Web Sites. Many corporations maintain web sites that may provide data on
manufacturing facilities. The level of detail varies greatly across owning companies: some
provide no information while others provide highly detailed facility information. Web
addresses for companies may be provided in some company data sources or obtained through
web searches via Internet search engines.

Other Sources. The Dun & Bradstreet Market Identifiers, American Business Disk,
and U.S. Manufacturers Database generally only provide location, sales, and employment
information. In addition, there are strict use limitations from these sources.

4-16


-------
Section 4 — Industry Profile Development

4.3.3.3 Firm Characterization

The profile must also characterize the potentially affected legal entities that own these
manufacturing facilities. As shown in Figure 4-1, the chain of ownership may be as simple as
one facility owned by one company (i.e., direct owner is parent company) or as complex as
one facility owned by multiple companies (i.e., direct owner is subsidiary company or other
legal entity). The legal entity of interest to the ISEG analyst is the ultimate parent company.
Sources of data to be used in characterizing these parent companies include the following:

•	InfoTrac—Information Access Company,

•	SEC 10-K reports (via EDGAR search),

•	Ward's Directory of U.S. Private and Public Companies,

•	Standard and Poor's Stock Report Services,

•	company annual reports and web sites, and

•	industry trade publications and journals.

Based on the appropriate SBA size definitions, the ISEG analyst must characterize the owning
firms by size to facilitate the future preparation of a regulatory flexibility analysis. For
example, under SIC 3312, the SBA defines a small company as one having 1,000 or fewer
employees. Therefore, based on the firms' sales or employment, the profile will identify the
firms owning potentially affected manufacturing plants as small or not small. This
characterization will also include an examination of vertical and horizontal integration that will
affect how the firms will respond to the regulation. The profile will also include data, where
possible, that will characterize the baseline financial condition of these companies, including
income statements, balance sheets, and cash flow statements.

The New York Public Library publishes a guide to doing basic research on United
States Companies that provides a fairly comprehensive list of company information resources.
This guide is available through the Internet at . Several of these sources can be classified as primary resources because
they have consistently been used to provide company-specific information for previous
industry profiles. In addition, other databases have also been identified as valuable sources of
industrywide financial information. Table 4-6 presents a summary of company-specific

4-17


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

resources, while Table 4-7 presents the data elements that they provide. Each source is briefly
described below.

ABC

Figure 4-1. Possible Ownership Configurations in U.S. Industries

4-18


-------
Section 4 — Industry Profile Development

Table 4-6. Summary of Company-Specific Sources

Identify Information by Company Type
Corporate 	

Data Source	Ownership Public Private Foreign Small

Information Access
Corporation®

VG

VG

G

P

F

Ward's Business
Directory

F

VG

G

P

F

Dun & Bradstreet
Market Identifiers11

VG

VG

VG

P

VG

Hoover's Online0

VG

VG

G

F

F

Worldscoped

*

F

P

VG

P

Standard & Poor's
Corporations'1

F

VG

VG

P

VG

Directory of Corporate
Affiliations

VG

G

F

VG

*

U.S. SEC/EDGAR
Database6

G

VG

NA

NA

*

Company Web Sites

G

G

F

F

F

VG =

very good

G =

good

F

fair

P

poor

NA =

not applicable

* =

unlikely to contain this information

a Information Access Corporation. 1997. Business & Company Profile ASAP, [computer file] Foster City,

CA: Information Access Corporation.
b Electronic database available through EPA's Facility Index System (FINDS).
c Nonsubscription service with web access via .
d Electronic access via CD-ROM.

e Nonsubscription service with web access via .

4-19


-------
Table 4-7. Data Elements for Company-Specific Sources



WWW

Legal Form

SIC





Income

Balance

Cash Flow

Data Source

Address

Organization

Codes

Sales

Employment

Statement

Sheet

Statement

Information Access Corporation®

X

X

X

X

X







Ward's Business Directory



X

X

X

X







Dun & Bradstreet Market Identifiers11





X

X

X







Hoover's Online0

X

X

X

X

X







Worldscoped



X

X

X

X







Standard & Poor's Corporations'1



X

X

X

X







Directory of Corporate Affiliations



X



X

X







U.S. SEC/EDGAR Database6



X

X

X

X

X

X

X

Company Web Sites

X





X

X

X

X

X

a Information Access Corporation. 1997. Business & Company Profile ASAP, [computer file] Foster City, CA: Information Access
Corporation.

b Electronic database available through EPA's Facility Index System (FINDS).
c Web access via .
d Electronic access via CD-ROM.
e Web access via .


-------
Section 4 — Industry Profile Development

The following sources provide information for specific companies of interest to the
economic analyst.

Information Access Company's Business Index. This electronic source allows the
user to search for individual companies by name or search for a list of companies in a
particular industry based on four-digit SIC codes. Once a company has been identified, this
source provides links to its corporate owner as well as recent articles about the company.

This database provides information on the company's legal form of organization, sales and
employment, and SIC codes. For some companies, the company's Internet address is also
included. Although this source is updated weekly, information for some companies may be
dated. The index is available at most university libraries or through the Internet at
. However, Internet access is restricted to subscribers.

Ward's Business Directory of U.S. and Private Companies. This print source allows
the user to search company names alphabetically or by a particular industry based on four-
digit SIC codes. The directory provides information on the company's legal form of
organization, sales and employment, and SIC codes. It also identifies the immediate owner of
the company, if applicable. The directory is published annually; however, the reported
information does not necessarily correspond to one particular time period. For example, the
1998 directory reports sales and employment information based and several years of data
(1994 through 1996).

Dun & Bradstreet (D&B) Database Available Through EPA 's Facility Index System
(FINDS). This electronic database allows the user to search for companies using a DUNS
identification number or company name. However, information on the state in which the
company is located is required to complete a company name search. Links to the ultimate
parent companies are provided, if available, as well as sales, employment, and SIC code
information. Although D&B is a good source of company data, there are strict use limitations
for this database.

Worldscope. This electronic database is very good source for information on
international companies. Users can search for companies by name and the database reports
sales, employment, and SIC code information. It also provides historical information for
company sales for the past 5 years.

4-21


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Standard and Poor's Corporations. This electronic database is an excellent source of
information on small and/or private companies. Users can search for companies by name or
SIC codes. It provides corporate ownership, sales, employment, and SIC information.

Hoover's Online. This electronic database is an excellent source of information on
U.S. public and private companies. Users can search for companies by name, ticker symbol,
or keyword. It provides corporate ownership, sales, net income, and employment. Links are
also provided to the company's web site and those of top competitors (if available), SEC
filings in EDGAR Online, investor research reports, and news and commentary.

Directory of Corporate Affiliations. This print source provides good information on
international corporations. Users can search an alphabetical list for company names. This
database identifies corporate ownership and reports sales and employment data. Information
is limited to larger corporations.

U.S. Security and Exchange Commissions: EDGAR Database. This source consists
of electronic filings by public corporations to the Securities and Exchange Commission (e.g.,
10-K reports) and is available through the Internet at .
Users can search by company name to locate appropriate reports. In addition to sales and
employment data, these reports typically include detailed financial information such as income
statements, balance sheets, and cash flow statements that are not available from other sources.
However, this source only includes information on publicly traded U.S. companies.

Corporate Web Sites. Many companies maintain web sites that can be good sources
of financial information. These sites often include recent annual reports and links to industry-
related sites. A starting point for searching for company web sites is
. However, individual company names can be searched using any Internet

search engine. As noted earlier, Information Access Company's Business Index also provides
Internet addresses for selected companies.

Sources containing information on industry financial conditions and trends often
provide general data that can be used to estimate missing data for specific companies. The
following resources may provide this type of information:

•	Dun & Bradstreet's Industry Norms & Key Business Ratios;

•	Leo Troy' s Almanac of Business and Industrial Financial Ratios;

4-22


-------
Section 4 — Industry Profile Development

•	Robert Morris Associates' Annual Statement Studies;

•	U.S. Department of Commerce's Quarterly Financial Reports for Manufacturing,
Mining, and Trade Corporations ; and

•	Value Line Publications' Value Line Investment Survey.

These sources should be available in print or electronic format at most academic or research
libraries.

4.3.3.4 Other Owning Entities

The profile must also characterize the other entities that are not firms but may own
affected facilities or emissions sources. These other entities include Federal agencies; state,
local, and tribal governments; and non-profit organizations. Table 4-8 provides several
resources that have been identified as providing information to characterize these owning
entities, including the following:

1992 Census of Governments: Government Finances-Compendium of Government
Finances. Presents statistics on governmental finances for Federal, state, and local
governments (separate tabulations are included for counties summarized by size). Data
include revenue by source, expenditures by function, per capita figures, percentage
distributions, and rankings. Finances of utilities operated by local governments are detailed by
state and by type of utility and government.

City Government Finances. Provides a summary of city government finances as well
as data on finances of city-operated utilities; supplementary detail on other utilities for
individual cities and selected urban towns and townships of over 75,000 population; city
finance items and per capita amounts of these items, by population-size groups; finances of
individual cities and selected urban towns and townships of over 75,000 population; per capita
amounts of financial items; and finances of individual city governments having 300,000
population or more.

County Government Finances. Provides a summary of county government finances
including data on revenue and expenditures, finances of county governments by population-
size groups, finances of individual county governments in counties of over 100,000
population, per capita amounts of selected financial items by counties, detailed finances of

4-23


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

individual counties of over 500,000 population, and finances of individual city-counties of
over 100,000 population.

To facilitate RFA and SBREFA analysis, based on the information obtained from these
sources and others, the industry profile will identify these other entities as small or not small.
In addition, some of the sources listed in Table 4-8 allow the analyst to characterize the
demographics and economic conditions within relevant governmental jurisdictions and
geographic areas.

4.3.4 Markets

This section of the profile provides historical and/or projected market data on U.S.
production, consumption, and foreign trade, as well as prices of affected commodities.

Table 4-9 provides several resources identified as providing such information. As shown,
these sources include statistical reports and trade articles published by trade associations and
government publications from the U.S. Department of Commerce, U.S. Department of
Energy, U.S. Geological Survey, and others. In addition, the U.S. International Trade
Commission periodically publishes industry profiles, which contain market data and
assessments of current and future market conditions for selected industries and/or products.
The primary sources of this type of information include the following:

•	Trade Associations. Trade associations often publish statistic reports that provide
historical and projected data on U.S. production/shipments and foreign trade.

Many of these associations have World Wide Web sites that provide online data
tables and text descriptions, publications lists, and links to other sources of data.

•	U.S. Bureau of Census. This government source provides publications and data
on U.S. economic activity and specific industries as identified by SIC codes. For
historical data on value and volume of U.S. shipments, the Census publications are
very good sources for numerous industries and products/services (available online
at .

•	U.S. Geological Survey. This government source provides publications and data
on the U.S. and global supply, demand, and flow of minerals and materials. For
most minerals and materials, this source provides historical data on U.S.
production, foreign trade, and apparent consumption, as well as market prices
(available online at !

4-24


-------
Section 4 — Industry Profile Development

Table 4-8. Summary of Sources to Characterize Other Owning Entities.

Source

Author/Provider and Availability

Revenues, Expenditures, Employment

1992 Census of Governments Titles®

1992 Census of Governments: Government
Finances—Compendium of Government
Finances11

City Government Finances, 1991-92°

County Government Finances, 1991-92d

Government Finances, 1991-926

Public Employment: Employment of Major
Local Governmentsf

Dept. of Commerce

http://www.census.gOv/prod/2/gov/gc92-4/gc924-5.pdf
Dept. of Commerce

http://www.census.gOv/prod-bin/pubgate.pl7/prod/2/gov/gc92-4/
gc924-5.pdf

Dept. of Commerce

http://www.census.gOv/prod/l/gov/gf92x8.pdf
Dept. of Commerce

http://www.census.gOv/prod/l/gov/gf92x5.pdf
Dept. of Commerce

http://www.census.gOv/prod-bin/pubgate.pl7/prod/2/gov/gc92-3/
gc923-2.pdf

Demographic and Other Economic Characteristics

County Business Patterns: 1993, 1994, and
1995s

Demographic and Economic State and
County Profiles'1

Regional Economic Information System:
1969-19961

National and State Population Estimates:
1990 to 1994J

Population Projections of the United States
by Age, Sex, Race, and Hispanic Origin:
1995 to 2050k

Population Projections for States: 1995 to
20251

Labor Force Characteristics of U.S.
Population"1

Characteristics of Business Owners
Database"

Dept. of Commerce

http://www.census.gov/prod/www/abs/cbptotal.html
Dept. of Commerce

http://www.census.gov/datamap/www/index.html

Bureau of Economic Analysis
http://govinfo.kerr.orst.edu/reis-stateis.html

Dept. of Commerce

http ://www .census. gov/prod/ 1/pop/p25-1127.pdf
Dept. of Commerce

http://www.census.gOv/prod-bin/pubgate.pl7/prod/l/pop/p25-1130/
Dept. of Commerce

http ://www .census. gov/prod-bin/pub gate .pl?/ftp/pub/prod/2/pop/
p25Zp25-1131.pdf

Dept. of Commerce

http://www.bls.census.gov/cps/cpsmain.htm
Dept. of Commerce

http://www.census.gov/econ/www/muQ400.html

U.S. Department of Commerce. 1992.
U.S. Department of Commerce. 1997.
U.S. Bureau of the Census. 1996.
U.S. Bureau of the Census. 1995.
U.S. Bureau of the Census. 1996.
U.S. Department of Commerce. 1997.
U.S. Department of Commerce. 1998.

U.S. Department of Commerce. 1999.
U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis. 1997.
Byerly, Edwin R, and Kevin Deardorff. 1995.
Day, Jennifer Cheeseman. 1996.

Campbell, Paul R. 1997.

U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 1996.
U.S. Bureau of the Census. 1996.

4-25


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

.a
—
"3

u
5

O

CD
c«
ce

Q

>
4>
-

4)

ce

s

ce

B

B
s
in

C\

-4-

4>

2

«
H

s

a>

S
—

w

CS

"ea
Q

oj	%

a	oj

^	£

S3	C

S	*

S ->

.Sf-o
fe *-

® h

to M

a a

3 SU

1 S

£ S.

2

C/5 m


o

bfi

s3



o

>

S3


o

bC
in
bD

£
£

f

V

ss

O

"S

C3

s

•c

Ph

O

>

o

o

>

CO
£

•>%

	.5

'5b	5

O	p"

*^3	^

o	o

w	I-*

o	§

•	P

CO	g

£	CQ

A
>
o

bp
flj
o

T3

cd

£
&

f

V

O

cd

"H
•c

CLh

a

>

a

>

o



c

0

1

5
o

C/)

cd

 bD





!l

8

bD

in

2

Qh

m
 O Uh Oh Z *

O

4-26


-------
Section 4 — Industry Profile Development

•	U.S. ITC Trade DataWeb. This government source provides U.S. imports and
exports by customized list of products to obtain value, quantity, and unit value for
products. (Version 1.7 of this database is currently available online at
).

•	Private Consulting Firm Studies. These studies may be a good source of historical
and projected data on U.S. production/shipments, foreign trade, and apparent
consumption. However, the analyst should be aware that the data provided in these
sources may be compilations of publicly available information and the methodology
or assumptions for projections are typically not provided in sufficient detail.

Other sources of this type of information include previous EPA investigations (i.e., profiles or
economic analyses) and survey articles in trade journals published by industry or academic
experts.

In addition to confirming the current status of the industry, these sources are often
useful in exploring trends and projections. Future projections are available from trade
associations, trade journals, government sources (e.g., U.S. Department of Energy forecasts), or
industry experts. The economic analyst should review the assumptions upon which the
forecasts are provided to determine the quality of these estimates and their validity given
acquired knowledge of the subject industry and/or markets. These assumptions should be
provided with the industry profile. Alternatively, the economic analyst can employ the historical
data to develop future growth projections based on simple growth rates or econometric
techniques using additional data on U.S. and global economic activity.

4-27


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

SECTION 5

EIA ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK AND OPERATIONAL ISSUES1

"Economic impact analysis" is not a precise term in economics but an evolving term
that describes the various analyses performed to gauge the economic consequences of EPA
regulations. Over time, conducting EIAs has become an integral part of ISEG's role in EPA's
regulatory development process. Based on legislative and administrative directives, the EIA's
purpose for ISEG is primarily to describe and quantify the reallocation of society's resources
in response to a proposed regulatory action. Under some circumstances, the EIA also
provides the social cost estimate to be compared with social benefits in the benefit-cost
analysis required in a full EA, as described in Section 2.

Generally, ISEG needs estimates of the following types of variables without and with
the regulation for the time period of the analysis:

•	facility- and industry-level impacts, which may include compliance cost burden;
revenue, cost, and profit changes; changes in capacity utilization; facility and
process closures; and employment changes;

•	market-level impacts, which may include changes in market prices, domestic
production and consumption, and foreign trade;

•	company-level impacts, which may include compliance cost burden and its impact
on financial viability and/or failure;

•	community-level impacts, which may include changes in employment, facility
closures, and changes in emissions;

•	governmental impacts, which may include the costs of administrative, monitoring,
and enforcement actions and changes in receipts from taxes or fees; and

•	social costs and benefits.

'For a more comprehensive review of the basic economic concepts of social cost, the reader may refer to the
document Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses prepared by EPA's Office of Policy (EPA, 1998d).
As of July 1998, that document was in draft form.

5-1


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

By quantifying and evaluating these impacts in the EIA, the ISEG analyst is able to provide
valuable inputs to policymakers in the regulatory development process and, if applicable,
improve the benefit-cost analysis.

The section continues with a description of the methodological approach for
performing EIAs in OAQPS. Section 5.1 provides a discussion of alternative approaches for
performing EIAs and the rationale for the partial equilibrium, intermediate-run market model
approach used in many ISEG analyses. Section 5.2 provides a conceptual overview of the
market modeling approach for estimating economic impacts. Section 5.3 moves beyond the
conceptual framework for market models to practical issues involved in developing an
economic model, when information on the economic phenomena of interest is often sketchy
and practical compromises must be made. Section 5.4 summarizes the analytical approach
and concludes with the recommended structure for organizing and reporting analytical results.

5.1 Alternative Approaches for Economic Impact Analysis

The analyst faces potentially four fundamental issues in selecting an analytical
approach for performing EIAs. The first is whether human behavioral responses are
incorporated in estimating economic impacts. If not, the remaining fundamental issues are
moot. If a behavioral approach is taken, the next issue is the extent to which market
relationships are modeled. The third is the length-of-run over which human and market
behavior is modeled. The fourth issue is whether a static or dynamic model is applied. Each
of these issues is discussed in turn below.

5.1.1 Behavioral vs. Nonbehavioral Models

The analyst can choose among two fundamentally different approaches in conducting

an EIA:

•	nonbehavioral: engineering and financial analysis of compliance costs, and

•	behavioral: analysis of economic responses to compliance requirements, usually in
a market setting

In both cases, "engineering" estimates of the costs of compliance for actual or model plants in
the regulated industry are the driving factor. With the nonbehavioral approach, the impacts of
the regulation are simply assumed to fall on the entities owning the facilities faced with the
compliance responsibilities. Analysis takes the form of gauging the severity of impacts,
typically using accounting measures of profit and loss. Alternatively, the behavioral approach

5-2


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

explicitly recognizes, for example, that owners of the affected facilities are economic agents
that can, and presumably will, make adjustments such as changing production rates or altering
input mixes that will generally affect the market environment in which they operate. One
likely market consequence is a change, typically a rise, in price that will then induce behavioral
responses by consumers and producers, which affect resource allocation.

Thus, the behavioral approach allows for a more realistic assessment of the
distribution of impacts across different groups within society than does the nonbehavioral
approach. More specifically, the nonbehavioral approach focuses the impacts entirely on the
entities directly affected by compliance requirements. The behavioral approach recognizes
that regulated entities will tend to shift at least some of the burden to other parties, such as
consumers or input suppliers. Thus, the nonbehavioral approach will tend to overstate the
impacts on the directly affected entities. Moreover, only the behavioral approach allows one
to appropriately estimate the potential price and international trade consequences of the
regulatory action. Finally, if the "cost" results from the EIA are to be used subsequently in
the benefit-cost analysis of an EA, then a conceptually correct measure of social costs should
include an assessment of behavioral responses (see OMB, 1996).

Recognizing the conceptual advantages and the underlying ability to provide the
information requirements of an EIA and EA, ISEG has traditionally employed the behavioral
economic model approach when feasible under data and other resource constraints. Given
this history, the discussion now moves to issues of market model scope and length of run.

5.1.2 Market Model Scope: Partial vs. General Equilibrium

A strictly partial equilibrium model tracks the effect of a regulatory action in one
market; all other possible market interactions are ignored. A strictly general equilibrium
model tracks the effects of a regulation in all sectors of the economy; no intersectoral linkages
are ignored. In between these two extremes are models that capture a finite set of pre-defined
important market linkages, ignoring effects in all other markets. These models are sometimes
referred to as "general" equilibrium models (e.g., Just, Hueth and Schmitz, 1982), but they
will be referred to here as multimarket partial equilibrium models.

Because the scope of many OAQPS regulatory actions is sector-specific and typically
not large enough to substantially affect other sectors of the economy, partial equilibrium
models are typically employed in estimating the economic impacts. These partial equilibrium
models may be strictly partial (one product market) or may be extended to multiple markets

5-3


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

when more than one market is directly affected by a regulation, and/or other related product
markets are potentially indirectly affected by the regulation.2 For example, the EIA conducted
for the Pulp and Paper Cluster rule modeled the interactions between the directly affected
markets for pulp inputs and the indirectly affected final paper and paperboard products.
Although these models may be extended to include multiple markets, they generally do not
account for interactions with the entire U.S. economy, as does the general equilibrium
approach.

5.1.3 Length-of-Run Considerations

In developing the partial equilibrium model, the analyst must determine the alternatives
available to economic agents in response to regulation and the context within which these
choices are made. This is largely dependent on the time horizon for which the analysis is
performed. Three benchmark time horizons are considered here: the very short run, the long
run, and the intermediate run.

5.1.3.1 Very Short Run

In the very short run, all factors of production are assumed to be fixed, leaving the
directly affected entity with no means to respond. Within a short time horizon, regulated
producers are constrained in their ability to adjust inputs or outputs due to contractual,
institutional, or other factors. In essence, this is equivalent to the nonbehavioral model
described earlier. Therefore, the impacts of the regulation fall entirely on the regulated entity.
Producers incur the entire regulatory burden as a one-to-one reduction in their profit. This is
referred to in the nomenclature of EIAs as the "full-cost absorption" scenario.

Unfortunately, there is no hard and fast rule for determining what length of time
constitutes the very short run. Nonetheless, under most conditions, economic entities have
some flexibility to adjust factors of production. And, as indicated above, ignoring those
adjustments tends to overstate producers' losses.

2In addition to product markets, multiple markets may also be defined based on geographic boundaries if
separate regionally distinct markets exist because of high transportation costs (e.g., cement, coke,
hazardous materials).

5-4


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

5.1.3.2 Long Run

In the fullness of time, all factors of production are variable and producers can be
expected to adjust production plans in response to cost changes imposed by a regulation.
Figure 5-1 illustrates a typical, if somewhat simplified, long-run industry supply function. The
function is horizontal, indicating that the marginal and average costs of production are
constant with respect to output.3 This horizontal slope reflects the fact that, under long-run
constant returns to scale, technology and input prices ultimately determine the market price,
not the level of output in the market.

Market demand is represented by the standard downward-sloping curve. The market
is assumed here to be perfectly competitive; equilibrium is determined by the intersection of
the supply and demand curves. The implications of imperfect competition on market
equilibrium are discussed below. In this case, the upward parallel shift in the market supply
curve represents the regulation's effect on production costs. The shift causes the market price
to increase by the full amount of the per-unit control cost (i.e., from P0 to P,). With the
quantity demanded sensitive to price, the increase in market price leads to a reduction in
output in the new with-regulation equilibrium (i.e., Q0 to Q,). As a result, consumers incur

Figure 5-1. Full-Cost Pass-Through of Regulatory Costs

3The constancy of marginal costs reflects an underlying assumption of constant returns to scale of production,
which may or may not apply in all cases.

5-5


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

the entire regulatory burden as represented by the loss in consumer surplus (i.e., the area P0 ac
Px). In the nomenclature of EIAs, this long-run scenario is typically referred to as "full-cost
pass- through."

Taken together, impacts modeled under the long-run/full-cost pass-through scenario
reveal an important point. Namely, under fairly general economic conditions, a regulation's
impact on producers is transitory. Ultimately, the costs are passed on to consumers in the form
of higher prices. However, this should not be used as a justification to completely dismiss
producer impacts in an EIA. For one, the long run may cover the time taken to retire all of
today's capital vintage—perhaps decades. Therefore, transitory impacts could be fairly
protracted. Given the call to discount the costs of a policy (see Section 8), transitory impacts
could dominate long-run impacts in terms of present value. Moreover, the statutes and EOs
referenced in Section 2 implicitly call for an assessment of impacts on current producers and
workers; thus, a purely long-run approach is moot for addressing transitory, but important,
concerns such as facility closures, capital displacement, and worker dislocation. Given the
previously referenced limits of a very short run perspective, the analyst should ideally consider
some intermediate case between the very short and long run to gauge economic impacts.

5.1.3.3 "Intermediate" Run

The "intermediate" run can best be defined by what it is not. It is not the very short
run and it is not the long run. In the intermediate-run, some factors are fixed; some are
variable.4 The existence of fixed production factors generally leads to diminishing returns to
those fixed factors. This typically manifests itself in the form of a marginal cost (supply)
function that rises with the output rate, as shown in Figure 5-2.

Again, the regulation causes an upward shift in the supply function. The lack of
resource mobility may cause producers to suffer profit (producer surplus) losses in the face of
regulation; however, producers are able to pass through the associated costs to consumers to
the extent the market will allow. As shown, in this case, the market-clearing process

4As a semantical matter, the situation where some factors are variable and some are fixed is often referred to as
the "short run" in economics, but the term "intermediate run" is used here to avoid any confusion with the
term "very short run."

5-6


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

$ g

Price
Increase

{

P,

P.

a

e

o

Increase

Sr With Regulation

S0: Without Regulation

Output

Figure 5-2. Partial-Cost Pass-Through of Regulatory Costs

generates an increase in price (from P0 to P,) that is less than the per-unit increase in costs
(fb), so that the regulatory burden is shared by producers (net reduction in profits) and
consumers (rise in price).

5.1.4 Static vs. Dynamic Models

At its core, the partial equilibrium model simulates a single period market outcome
without and with regulation. Each solution of the model is, therefore, static in nature. The
model can, in principle, be extended to incorporate temporal dynamics such as exit and entry
over time and adoption of new technology. Then, time paths of market equilibria without and
with the regulation can be simulated to track regulatory effects over time. This approach has
some obvious attractions but is typically difficult to implement. Dynamic models of firm
entry, exit, and technological change are difficult to estimate and generally quite sensitive to
model specification and parameter values. Therefore, the common practice is to stimulate
regulatory effects in a static setting, using a representative year as the basis for estimating
annual regulatory impacts. More information on selecting the analytical baseline and time
period of analysis is presented in Section 8.

5-7


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

5.1.5 Standard Approach for ISEG Industry-Level Analyses

The remainder of this section focuses on EIAs conducted for regulations of existing
sources in a single regulated industry. This single-industry focus characterizes rulemakings
such as the imposition of a MACT standard for a NESHAP. The standard approach for
addressing these problems is the development and application of partial equilibrium/
intermediate-run/static (PEIS) models to assess impacts in the potentially affected market(s).
The role of new sources and the impacts of new source performance standards, while not part
of this document's focus, can easily be accommodated within the methods described here.
However, that is not the case for industry-specific regulations that have costs large enough to
substantially affect other sectors or regulations, such as NAAQS standards, that cut
extensively across industries. Those extensive regulations need more serious consideration of
general equilibrium and macroeconomic models to appropriately gauge economic impacts.5
Those modeling topics are beyond the scope of the current document but may be included in
future revised editions. Thus, the section continues by describing the conceptual
underpinnings of the PEIS modeling approach.

5.2 PEIS Modeling Approach: Conceptual Framework

This section examines the impact of the regulations that affect the production costs for
facilities in an affected industry. It provides an overview of the basic economic theory of the
effect of the regulations on facility production decisions and the concomitant effect on market
outcomes. The framework presented here employs standard concepts in microeconomics to
model the supply of affected products and the impacts of the regulations on production costs
and the operating decisions. The three main elements are

•	regulatory effects on the manufacturing facility,

•	market responses, and

•	facility-market interactions.

'Although general equilibrium and dynamic aspects of the effects of regulation are not addressed explicitly in
this section, these aspects certainly influence the magnitude and distribution of the regulatory burden (e.g.,
see Hazilla and Kopp, 1990). However, in the case of MACT standards, they are deemed by the analyst as
having second-order impacts that are generally not worth the additional time and resources to formally
address in the EIA model. Alternatively, some of these influences are addressed separately as described
more fully in Section 8.

5-8


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

The remainder of this section describes each of these main elements.

5.2.1 Facility-Level Effects

At any point in time, the costs that an existing facility faces can be classified as either
unavoidable (sunk) or avoidable. In the former category, we include costs to which the firm is
committed and that must be paid regardless of any future actions of the firm. For instance,
debt incurred to construct a production facility must be repaid regardless of the facility's
production plan and even if the facility ceases operation prior to full repayment, unless the
range of viable alternatives includes the declaration of bankruptcy by the owners. The second
category, avoidable costs, describes any costs that are foregone by ceasing production. These
can be further refined to distinguish between costs that vary with the level of production and
those that are independent of the production level. For example, production factors such as
labor, materials, and capital (except in the short run) vary with the level of output, whereas
expenditures for facility security and administration may be independent of production levels,
but avoidable if the facility closes down. The determination of both the avoidability and the
variability of firms' costs is essential to the analysis of economic responses to the proposed
regulations.

The current technical features of these facilities reflect the historical economic
environment and managerial decisions of the firm. The existence of the fixed factors give rise
to (eventually) diminishing marginal returns to production and, along with the terms under
which the firm may purchase variable inputs, condition the shape of the cost curve of the
facility. Figure 5-3 illustrates the derivation of a facility supply function for a subject product
from the classical U-shaped structure of production costs with respect to output. Let AVAC
be the facility's average variable (avoidable) cost curve and AT AC the average total
(avoidable) cost curve for producing the product. The vertical distance between ATAC and
AVAC is the per-unit average cost of nonvariable avoidable costs, which approaches zero as
the number of units of output increases. MC is the marginal cost of producing the product,
which intersects AVAC and ATAC at their respective minimum points. All these curves are
drawn conditional on input prices and the technology in place at the facility.

Managers of existing facilities face operating decisions of whether to operate at all
and, if so, the optimal rate of output. Depending on market structure, they may also face
choices in the prices they pay for purchased inputs and the price they charge for their

5-9


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

produced commodity. The facility supply function is the section of the marginal cost curve
bounded by the quantities qm and qM. qm is the minimum economically feasible production
rate that is determined by the minimum of the AVAC curve, which coincides with the price
pm. Suppose the market price of the subject product is less than pm. qM is the largest feasible
production rate that can be sustained at the facility given the technology and other fixed
factors in place, regardless of the output price. In this case, the firm's best response is to
close the facility and not produce because P < ATAC implies that total revenue would be less
than total costs if the facility operated at the associated output levels below qm. Based on
profit-maximizing behavior, these managers will select the output rate where the additional
contribution of output to revenue (marginal revenue or MR) is equated to its additional
contribution to cost (marginal cost or MC). For facilities competing in perfectly competitive
markets this is where market price equals marginal cost, that is, at [P*, Q*] in Figure 5-3.
Profits or quasi-rents are the difference between total revenues and total costs. This reflects
annual return to the fixed factors and, as pointed out by Friedman (1962), is a consequence of
the firm's operating decision, not a determinant of it. The fixed and variable costs
("contractual costs" in Friedman's terminology) are the determinants of the equilibrium
(profit-maximizing) output rate.

MC

Figure 5-3. Product Supply Function at Facility

5-10


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

Now consider the effect of the proposed regulatory control costs. These fall into one
of two categories: avoidable variable and avoidable nonvariable. These proposed costs are
characterized as avoidable because a firm can choose to cease operation of the facility and,
thus, avoid incurring the costs of compliance. The variable control costs include the operating
and maintenance costs of the controls, while the nonvariable costs include compliance capital
equipment. Figure 5-4 illustrates the effect of these additional costs on the facility supply
function. The facility's AVAC and MC curves shift upward (to AVAC' and MC') by the
per-unit variable compliance costs. In addition, the nonvariable compliance costs increase
total avoidable costs and, thus, the vertical distance between ATAC' and AVAC'. The
facility's supply curve shifts upward with marginal costs and the new (higher) minimum
operating level (qm/) is determined by a new (higher) pm/.

5.2.2 Market Effects

To facilitate this discussion, it is assumed that prices for the commodities affected by
regulation are determined in competitive markets. In this case, the individual facilities have
negligible power over the market price and, thus, take the price as "given" by the market.
The market supply curve is defined as the horizontal summation of the individual facility

Figure 5-4. Effect of Compliance Costs on Product Supply Function at Facility

5-11


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

supply curves, and a market demand curve is the sum of the demand curves for all demanders
of the product. As shown in Figure 5-5(a), under perfect competition, market prices and
quantities are determined by the intersection of market supply and demand curves. The initial
baseline scenario consists of a market price and quantity (P, Q) that is determined by the
downward-sloping market demand curve (DM) and the upward-sloping market supply curve
(SM) that reflects the sum of the individual supply curves of affected as well as unaffected
facilities.

Now consider the effect of the regulation on the baseline scenario as shown in
Figure 5-5(b). In the baseline scenario without the proposed standards, at the projected price,
P, the industry would produce total output, Q, with affected facilities producing the amount
qa and unaffected facilities accounting for Q minus qa, or qu. The regulation raises the
production costs at affected facilities, causing their supply curves to shift upward from Sa to
Sa' and the market supply curve to shift upward to SM. At the new with-regulation
equilibrium, the market price increases from P to P' and market output (as determined from
the market demand curve, DM) declines from Q to Q'. This reduction in market output is the
net result from reductions at affected facilities and increases at unaffected facilities.
Unaffected facilities will not face an upward shift in their product supply curves, so their
response to higher product prices is to increase production. Foreign suppliers (i.e., imports),
which do not incur higher production costs due to the regulations, will respond in the same
manner as these unaffected producers.

5.2.3 Facility-Level Response to Compliance Costs and New Market Prices

The firm's response to a proposed regulatory action is both facilitated and constrained
by commodity and financial market relationships that make up the economic system. The
firm's adjustments discussed above reflect efforts to respond to the regulation in a profit-
maximizing fashion. This may lead, for example, to changes in output that, when aggregated
across all producers, lead to changes in the market-clearing price and feedback on the firms to
alter their decisions. These adjustments are typically characterized as a simultaneous
interaction of producers, consumers, and markets. Thus, to evaluate the facility-market
outcomes the analysis must go beyond the initial effect of the regulation and project the net
effect after the market(s) has adjusted.

5-12


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

Market

Affected Facilities	Unaffected Facilities

a) Baseline Equilibrium

Market

Affected Facilities	Unaffected Facilities

b) With Regulation Equilibrium
Figure 5-5. Market Equilibrium Without and With Regulation

5-13


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Given changes in market prices and costs, the facility operator will elect to either

•	comply with the regulation and continue to operate, adjusting production and input
use based on new revenues and costs, or

•	cease production at the facility and exit the market.

These options can be extended to the multiproduct facility where product lines may be closed
if product revenues are less than product-specific avoidable costs, and/or the entire facility
may be closed if total revenues from all products do not exceed facility-specific avoidable
costs.

Therefore, after the interaction of facility and market forces is considered, the
operating decisions at each individual facility can be derived. These operating decisions
include whether to continue to operate the facility (i.e., closure) and, if so, the optimal
production level based on compliance costs and new market prices. The approach to
modeling the facility closure decision is based on conventional microeconomic theory. This
approach compares the ATAC—which includes all cost components that fall to zero when
production discontinues—to the expected post-regulatory price. Figure 5-4 illustrates this
comparison. If price falls below the ATAC, total revenue would be less than the total
avoidable costs. In this situation, the owner's cost-minimizing response is to close the facility.
Therefore, as long as there is some return to the fixed factors of production, that is some
positive level of profits, the firm is expected to continue to operate the facility.

If the firm decides to continue operations, then the facility's decision turns to the
optimal output rate. Facility and product-line closures, of course, directly translate into
reductions in output. However, the output of facilities that continue to operate will also
change depending on the relative impact of compliance costs and higher market prices.
Increases in costs will tend to reduce producers' output rates; however, some of this effect is
mitigated when prices are increased. If the market price increase more than offsets the
increase in unit costs, then even some affected facilities could respond by increasing their
production. Similarly, supply from unaffected domestic producers and foreign sources will
respond positively to changes in market prices.

The approach described above provides a realistic and comprehensive view of the
effect of the regulations on responses at the facility level as well as the corresponding effect
on market prices and quantities for the affected commodities. This is a substantial
improvement over analytical methods that do not account for facility-level responses such as

5-14


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

quantity adjustments, input adjustments, and closure of product lines, or methods that ignore
the effect of these regulations on market prices when determining the change in revenues and
costs at the facility level. Methods that do not allow for production adjustments at the facility
level essentially assume that firms cannot or will not adjust to changes in production costs.
Without responses at the facility level, no credible model for a change in market prices as a
result of the regulations exists. Both of these assertions—unresponsiveness of firms to market
conditions and market price changes in response to regulation—seem unwarranted by
observation.

5.3 PEIS Modeling Approach: Operational Issues

This section addresses the practical issues that must be resolved to provide an
empirical analysis of economic impacts and social costs using the behavioral approach. The
key information needed to develop this approach relates to the baseline characterization of
affected producers and markets, engineering estimates of the regulatory control cost for
affected entities, and modeling of the economic behavior of affected entities (e.g., position and
shape of the supply and demand functions) and market outcomes.

5.3.1 Baseline Characterization

To perform the economic impact analysis, the model must allow for a comparison
between the baseline equilibrium conditions and the counterfactual or with-regulation
equilibrium conditions that the model produces under a changed policy regime. The
assumption of an "observable" baseline equilibrium leads directly to the need for and
construction of a data set that fulfills the equilibrium conditions for the industry or entities
subject to a regulatory action. The issues of selecting and specifying the time period of
analysis are discussed in detail in Section 8. This section addresses how to develop an
analytical baseline that appropriately accounts for the entities, products, and markets to be
affected by a regulatory action in a manner consistent with the available data from the industry
profile and engineering cost analysis. Based on the EIA conducted for the Polymers and
Resins IINESHAP, Table 5-1 provides an example of the typical components of a baseline
scenario for use in an EIA.

5-15


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Table 5-1. Baseline Characterization of U.S. Amino and Phenolic Resin Markets: 1991



Amino Resins

Phenolic Resins

Market price ($/lb)

$0.26

$0.49

Market quantity(million lbs/yr)a

1,715.1

2,694.0

Domestic production

1,679.0

2,658.0

Affected

1,091.8

2,479.3

Unaffected

587.2

178.7

Exports

50.7

92.7

Imports

25.0

36.0

a Market quantity is the sum of domestic production and imports (exports are included within domestic
production).

Another case where the analyst will need different measures of regulatory impact
occurs when the regulatory action affects a factor of production (e.g., boilers or degreasers).
In the majority of these cases, data are not sufficient for the analyst to model the final product
markets or there are too many markets to be modeled. The direct impact measures most often
used in these cases address the relative impact of the costs imposed on these inputs and the
ultimate burden placed on users of these inputs (i.e., producers of final product). These
measures include the following:

•	annual control cost share of annual costs for the affected factor(s) and

•	annual control cost share of value of shipments of the final product.

In lieu of a market analysis, the first measure above can be used to determine the likelihood
that the factor will be substituted away from by the producer (i.e., comparison with costs of
substitute inputs/processes), while the second measure can be used to project potential price
increases to consumers of the final good or service (see the EIA conducted for NSPS on
utility and industrial boilers).

5.3.1.1 Producer Characterization

The industry profile and industry responses to the EPA's Information Collection
Request (ICR) form the basis for identifying and characterizing all known sources in the
affected industry (e.g., manufacturing facilities or plants) or other affected entities (e.g.,

5-16


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

federal, state, or local governments). For inclusion in the economic model, these potentially
affected entities must be either individually characterized or grouped together in terms of their
technical and economic activities. The level of resolution for which these entities are included
in the EIA depends on the data available from the industry profile and ICR survey and the
engineering cost analysis methodology. Obviously, the economic analysis cannot identify and
characterize the known sources beyond the limits imposed by the available data from the
industry profile or ICR survey responses. However, a less obvious constraint on the
economic analysis involves the level at which EPA is able to estimate the compliance costs of
the regulatory action.

The most detailed and accurate method to determine compliance costs is to examine
the requirements of each individual entity in the affected industry. Thus, the best case
scenario occurs when the economic and engineering analysis are not limited in their ability to
fully characterize individual facilities. If data are not sufficient to determine facility-specific
requirements, the next best approach is to estimate these costs for model plants and to map
the model plants (and related control costs) directly to actual facilities. If model plants are
used, then they should appropriately capture all types of facility characteristics in the industry
without any unnecessary limits (e.g., production process, capacity, vintage). The economic
analyst should review the characterization of model plants and assignment to the industry to
verify that it agrees with industry structure (as set out in the industry profile). Again, in this
case, individual facilities are able to be fully characterized.6 However, in cases where the
number of affected entities is very large (e.g., 20,000 dry cleaners) and/or limited information
is available, the model plant costs may be allocated to facility groupings based on a
distribution rule (e.g., one-third of the affected facilities are represented by model plant A). In
this case, the economic analyst is limited by the engineering analysis and can only characterize
groups of suppliers within the affected industry. Similarly, those entities that are not directly
affected by the regulatory action may be grouped together and modeled with single
representative agents.

In addition, other economic considerations should be accounted for in characterizing
affected entities. These considerations include issues such as the scale and scope of
production. Potentially affected producers may be part of vertically integrated operations in
which the directly affected product is captively produced and consumed within the firm for

6This scenario is the most often available and employed in conducting EIAs within ISEG.

5-17


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

use in the production of another intermediate or final product. For example, the pulp and
paper industry is characterized by both nonintegrated and vertically integrated mills.

Vertically integrated mills rely mostly on their own production of pulp to produce paper and
paperboard products, while nonintegrated mills include pulp mills that produce market pulp as
well as paper mills that purchase market pulp to produce paper and paperboard products.
Thus, in conducting the EIA for the Pulp and Paper Cluster Rule, the ISEG analysts
categorized mills in this manner to appropriately define their market activities and interactions
(i.e., supplier versus demander) and, thus, better estimate the economic impacts.

Furthermore, in the case of joint production, the specification of product lines at affected
facilities depends not only on the available industry profile or survey data but also on the
resolution of compliance cost estimates. For example, in the Pulp and Paper EIA, the
integrated and paper-only mills jointly produced a myriad of final paper and paperboard
products. The level at which the economic model addressed the production of individual
product lines was determined by the ability of the engineers or economic analysts to
appropriately assign or allocate compliance costs at a given mill across its products.

5.3.1.2 Market Characterization

In the cases where markets are well defined and impacts clearly should be addressed,
the EIA evaluates the economic impacts in terms of market adjustments and the associated
producer and consumer surplus measures welfare change, as described in Section 5.3. The
market characterization process involves two main activities

1.	Determining the markets that are affected by the regulation

2.	Determining the competitive structure of affected markets

The determination of markets potentially affected by the regulation requires identifying
the products that are produced at the affected facilities and linking them with specific markets
in which they are traded. The product identification process will be determined to some
extent by self-evidence (e.g., regulation of the Portland cement industry) and to some extent
by the availability of product-level data at the affected facilities. The latter may occur either
through the Agency information collection process or, in some cases, by secondary data.7

7For example, the pulp and paper industry produces a publication called Lockwood Post's Directory that
provides some link between facilities and the type of products they produce.

5-18


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

Once affected products are identified, linking them to markets requires a clean
definition of the relevant markets. For the purposes of this discussion, markets can be defined
along the dimensions of substitutability and geography.8

The extent to which products serve as close substitutes has a large effect on whether
they should be considered part of the same market. For instance, two herbicide products that
are both used on corn are fairly close substitutes and would normally be considered in the
same market. However, herbicides for corn and steel beams are not substitutes and would not
be considered in the same market. The analyst is often aided in the market definition task by
the existence of standard industry and product codes where substitutability is implicit in the
definitions (e.g. SIC codes). In addition, industry trade publications often provide information
on end use markets that is more detailed than SIC codes.

Once the analyst has determined the substitution dimension, the geographic extent of
the markets must be defined. In many cases, the argument can be made for national markets
for potentially affected products. However, regional or local markets may exist for products
where the ability of producers to compete across regions is limited by physical or economic
barriers to transport the product (e.g., cement and dry cleaning). In such cases, these
regional or more localized markets should be defined and characterized to the extent available
data allow.

Once the potentially affected markets are defined, the economic analyst must
determine the practicality of including all potentially affected markets in the economic model.
To aid in this determination, a screening analysis can be employed to avoid unnecessary
inclusion of too few or too many markets. For example, information on the proportion of all
producers (output, capacity) in the market that are potentially affected and the relative
magnitude of their compliance costs can provide some insights on the merits of including that
market in the analysis. In general, observing smaller proportions of affected producers and/or
relative compliance costs reduces the value of modeling a particular market. In some cases,
the screening analysis may suggest little need to conduct a market analysis altogether; that is,
no market adjustment is expected in response to regulation or the expected adjustment is small
enough to ignore.

8This follows early guidance on market definition by Stigler (1955) and Scherer (1980). See Viscusi, Vernon,
and Harrington (1992, p. 148-149) for a synopsis of the market definition issue.

5-19


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

For all markets that will be modeled, the analyst must characterize the degree of
competition within these markets. The discussion generally focuses on perfect competition,
or price-taking behavior, and imperfect competition, or the lack of price-taking behavior.
Although most EIAs conducted by ISEG involve perfectly competitive markets (or, at least,
assume this market structure), some EIAs have been conducted for imperfectly competitive
industries, such as pharmaceuticals and cement. In fact, the OMB guidelines for EO 12866
specifically mention that elements of market power should be addressed in conducting EAs
and measuring the social costs of regulatory actions. Therefore, it is important for the
economic analyst to select the appropriate market structure for the subject industry because
the projected market outcomes can vary greatly by specification of market structure.9

5.3.1.3 Characterizing Impacts Outside a Market Setting

In cases where markets are not well defined or impacts are negligible and not explicitly
addressed, the analyst needs different measures of regulatory impact. The majority of these
cases occur when a regulatory action directly affects government-owned10 and nonprofit11
entities by imposing control requirements and the associated compliance costs (e.g., landfills,
municipal waste combustors [MWCs], publicly owned sewerage treatment works [POTWs],
municipally owned electric companies).12 The direct impact measures most often used in these
cases address the relative impact of the costs imposed on these entities and the burden placed
on citizens or consumers of the affected services. These measures include the following:

•	annual control cost share of annual costs for the affected service(s),

•	annual control cost share of annual revenues of the governmental unit, and

•	per-household (or per capita) annual control cost share of median household (or
per capita) income.

9See Research Triangle Institute (1996b) for discussion of market structure and its importance in conducting
EIAs.

'"Potentially affected government entities include states, cities, counties, towns, townships, water authorities,
villages, Indian Tribes, special districts, and military bases.

"Potentially affected nonprofit entities include nonprofit hospitals, colleges and universities, and research
institutions.

12The indirect impacts of a regulatory action on government entities are addressed separately in Section 5.3
(federal administrative, monitoring, and enforcement) and Section 8 (UMRA-related).

5-20


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

For some affected services, in lieu of a market analysis, the first measure above can be used to
project increases in fees charged to local consumers of the service (see the EIA conducted for
MWCs) or the likelihood that the service will be discontinued by the governmental agency
(i.e., use of closure decision similar to that for private firms). In addition, baseline measures
of the economic and financial status of the affected entity or community can provide insights
on their ability to absorb the required expenditures.

5.3.2 Regulatory Control Costs

Before an EIA can be performed, quantitative estimates must be made of the control
costs that will be incurred by the affected entities in complying with the regulatory
alternatives. For stationary sources, pollution control cost estimates are typically developed
by the Emission Standards Division (ESD). These cost estimates are determined for each
control option and modified for any source-specific factors to estimate the compliance cost
per source. The ESD analysis sums the source-specific costs to compute the aggregate, or
national, compliance cost. Economic analysts (working for ISEG), in turn, use these costs to
evaluate the economic and financial impacts of a regulatory action. The use of these costs for
the EIA is summarized below.

As shown in Table 5-2, the engineering analysis typically estimates both fixed and
variable control costs for each regulatory alternative. Fixed control costs include the costs
associated with purchasing and installing pollution control equipment and other costs that are
periodically recurring but do not vary with the level of emissions or production (e.g., fixed
overhead, property taxes, insurance, and other administrative costs). Alternatively, those
control costs that do vary with the level of emissions or production include the regularly
recurring expenditures required to operate the control equipment as well as any costs incurred
due to a change in operating practices as a result of regulatory action. For example, if a
facility uses a substitute input in response to a regulatory action, the additional annual costs
associated with using the substitute are included in the operating cost component. Net
operating costs may include credits for reduced consumption of energy or material resources
associated with pollution control. Also shown in Table 5-2 are monitoring, reporting, and
recordkeeping (MR&R) costs. These costs may have a variable and/or fixed component. In
absence of engineering determination of these components, these costs are typically included
with other fixed costs.

5-21


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Table 5-2. Required Compliance Cost Elements for Affected Entities

Fixed control costs (do not vary with emissions level)

Capital investment

Initial capital cost (total installed costs of compliance equipment)
Annualized capital (include separate info on equipment life and interest rate)
Other fixed costs

Overhead allocation
Property taxes
Insurance

Administrative fees/charges
Variable control costs (vary with output level)

Raw materials
Process
Maintenance
Energy/utilities
Labor

Waste treatment disposal fees
Replacement parts

Product recovery factors (may lead to cost savings)

Monitoring, reporting, and recordkeeping costs (may have fixed and variable components)

The engineering estimates of fixed capital and variable operating and maintenance
(O&M) costs provide the measure of total annual compliance costs without accounting for
behavioral responses. Annualized costs represent the total yearly pollution control
expenditures and consist of the sum of the annual O&M control cost and the annualized
capital control cost. To compute the annualized capital control cost, partitioning the capital
cost into the equivalent of annual payments is necessary so that the total capital cost is not
assessed against any single year in the operational life of the control equipment (see

5-22


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

Figure 5-6). The capital costs are annualized over the expected lifetime of the capital
equipment using the opportunity cost of capital.13 Although firm-specific costs of capital are
desired for this approach, these rates are difficult to obtain from publicly available sources and
are not generally available for use in the EIA. Therefore, in the absence of firm-specific
estimates of the cost of capital, the EIA typically uses 7 percent based on the OMB Circular
A-94. Please see the discussion in Section 8 on discounting for more information on the
appropriate cost of capital to annualize capital investment required by regulation.

The total annualized control cost estimated for each affected entity is calculated on a
per unit of output basis, typically the quantity of the good/service provided. These average
control cost estimates are used in the economic impact modeling to project market
adjustments in response to a regulatory action. However, it is important to note that the
method used in the engineering analysis to estimate control costs and the magnitude of these
estimates will affect the way in which the economic analyst is able to conduct the EIA.
Specifically, the engineering analysis may affect the way in which the economic analysis is able
to model the affected entities and markets. As discussed above, the economic analyst must
consider the preliminary engineering cost estimates in developing the appropriate economic
methodology.

5.3.3 Modeling Economic Behavior

Building from the baseline characterization and regulatory control costs (as described
above), the ISEG analyst can employ standard concepts in microeconomics to develop the
behavioral economic model. The main elements are

•	characterize supply of each product at the individual and market levels,

•	characterize demand for each product, and

•	solve for the new with-regulation equilibrium.

This section provides an overview of these key operational issues in conducting EIAs.

13This approach is based on the properties of compound interest and the related concept of an annuity. The
value of the annuity is the amount, which, if it is charged as a cost each year over the control equipment's
useful life, will result in a present value equal to the total capital cost. In other words, the total capital cost
will be recovered if the annuity is charged year by year for the lifetime of the control equipment. This
recovered amount includes the principal value plus a return on the principal. The expected rate of return
on the principal is referred to as the opportunity cost of capital, or simply the cost of capital (where capital
refers to investment funds rather than equipment).

5-23


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

S/year

• Year

a) Actual Cash Outlays for Pollution Control

S/year

Year

b) Annualized Costs for Pollution Control

1 1 Installed Capital Costs

| | Annualized Capital Costs

| | \ ii nual Operating Costs



Figure 5-6. Actual and Annualized Estimates of Compliance Costs

5-24


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

5.3.3.1 Supply Characterization and Responses

Historically, most of the EIAs prepared by ISEG have been applied in situations where
supply side issues have been critical. In these cases, implementation of a proposed regulatory
action will affect the costs of production at existing sources of air emissions, which is
expected to induce some facilities to alter their current level of production or to close. As a
result, much of the attention has been placed on using information from the engineering
analysis and industry profiles to characterize supply from potentially affected entities. The
need to specifically address the distribution of producer impacts pursuant to RFA/SBREFA
and UMRA suggests that supply-side factors will become even more prominent in future
analyses.

Supply Function Specification. The supply function relates the quantity of a good
supplied as a function of its price and other factors, such as the price of inputs, the price of
substitute outputs, and technological factors. As with the demand function, factors other than
the product's price are typically held constant in the supply analysis. Therefore, the focus of
the supply function specification is to establish the quantitative relationship between price and
quantity supplied in the affected market. The market-level supply functions presented in the
conceptual discussion can be viewed as the aggregate sum of the supply functions of all
individual suppliers in the market. The change in market supply in response to price then is
the sum of all suppliers' responses to price.

First consider the polar case of the horizontal market supply function presented in
Figure 5-7. In this case, all suppliers in the market have identical and constant marginal cost
of production. Therefore, it is assumed that the market can supply an unlimited supply of
product X at the given unit cost. This implies that all suppliers are identical (possess the same
production technology) and that no factors raise marginal cost as output increases (e.g.,
diminishing returns to a fixed capital stock, inclusion of higher cost supply sources as market
output expands). This type of supply function is often associated with the long run where
technology and input prices ultimately determine the market price, not the level of output in
the market. Given the previously referenced problems with taking a purely long-run view in
the analysis of economic impacts, the horizontal aggregate supply function is, nonetheless,
sometimes all that the data can support. In those cases, all that is needed is the baseline price
level and the assumption that supply is perfectly elastic at that price. This may be further
supplemented with data on baseline costs of production and output levels to compute average

5-25


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

$/q

S

q/t

Figure 5-7. Horizontal Supply Curve

cost levels and compare with price. If market price and average cost differ substantially, this
may cast some doubt on the validity of the horizontal supply function.

Alternatives to the horizontal supply function include the following:

•	econometric estimation of supply,

•	prototype supply function with parameter inputs, and

•	step supply function.

The first option, econometric estimation, uses econometric methods applied to data on
producer quantities, price, and the other theoretically relevant variables. For example, in
conducting the EIA for the Pulp and Paper Cluster Rule, the Agency econometrically
estimated product-specific supply curves for each affected commodity based on pooled
time-series, cross-sectional production data for each affect facility. An additional econometric
approach is simultaneous estimation of supply and demand systems (see Kennedy [1994] for
an overview). Direct econometric estimation of supply functions has theoretical and empirical
appeal but may be difficult to implement due to data and project resource limitations.

5-26


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

Moreover, estimation of only an aggregate market supply function will not allow for direct
mapping of impacts to individual suppliers that may be differentially affected by the regulation.

The solution to the econometric implementation and producer heterogeneity issues just
referenced may come in the form of characterizing the aggregate supply function as a
collection of prototype supply functions, each of which captures a distinct segment of the
supply side of the market. For example, a Cobb-Douglass specification is

Q;s = bP e	(5.1)

where i indexes each supply segment modeled. The price elasticity of supply is given by e,
and b is a parameter representing the scale of the output-price relationship. In the extreme,
there is a unique supply function for each supplier (firm, facility) in the market. More
typically, there will be distinct model supply units characterized by factors such as technology,
region, or other characteristics that differentiate supply conditions. This upward-sloping
supply curve is illustrated in Figure 5-8. Based on the selected functional form, the economic
analyst then proceeds to the issue of parameter estimation.14 Supply function elasticity
parameters can be econometrically estimated or based on previous econometric estimates in
the literature. However, in the absence of these estimates, assumed elasticity values for the
commodities of interest may be used and are good candidates for sensitivity analysis.15

While the collective prototype functions approach has the advantage of accounting for
differences across suppliers, there may be conceptual or empirical reasons arguing against the
use of smooth continuous upward-sloping supply functions as shown in Figure 5-8 to
represent each supply unit. These might include inflexible production processes not easily
varied in response to prices and binding capacity constraints. If such concerns are warranted,

"Ideally, the economic analyst would base the selection of functional form on technical aspects of the subject
production process(es) affected by regulation to appropriately model producer behavioral responses.
Because these technical aspects often do not directly relate to a particular functional form, the analyst is
left to select from the most commonly used general forms such as Cobb-Douglas, constant elasticity of
substitution (CES), Leontief, and Generalized Leontief. These mathematical forms can be found in
intermediate or advanced texts in applied production theory (Chambers, 1988).

15One textbook on economic analysis of environmental regulation refers to this problem as the absence of an
encyclopedic Book of Elasticities to which the analyst can always refer to get the appropriate parameter
(Arnold, 1995, page 20). That textbook provides a very useful discussion of practical modeling issues
confronted in performing OPPT's EA for the asbestos rule.

5-27


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Figure 5-8. Upward-Sloping Supply Curve

then one instead can use a step supply function approach, as illustrated in Figure 5-9. Here,
Step 1 represents the average cost of supply for producer 1, the lowest cost supplier. For any
price at or above Pl3 producer 1 is assumed to supply a fixed amount of output, Q,.

Supplier 2 is the next lowest cost supplier and will provide Q2 for any price at or above P2. As
the price rises, more steps (higher-cost suppliers and quantities) are brought into the market
and output expands. Based on this approach, the marginal producer defines the market price
(i.e., the highest observed average variable cost of production is assumed to be the baseline
market price).

Employing a step supply function requires information on the opportunity cost and
output level for all potential suppliers (or model supply segments) in the market. In the short
run, opportunity costs may be crudely approximated by the average variable cost (AVC) of
production. These data may be difficult to obtain for individual suppliers in the market
because of confidentiality constraints, unless the data were obtained through an ICR and
maintained through Confidential Business Information (CBI) procedures. In other situations,
secondary data may be available through industry or government sources to approximate costs
by supplier type. Examples of this approach include the engineering cost analysis conducted

5-28


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

$/Output

Pi

Qi

Q,

Q,

CL

Q,

Q6 Output/t

Figure 5-9. Step Supply Function

to estimate baseline AVC for individual coke batteries for use in the Coke Ovens EIA
(Research Triangle Institute, 1992) and the fixed coefficient AVC function estimated for
individual cement kilns for use in the Portland cement EIA (Research Triangle Institute,
1996a). An additional method described in Arnold's (1995) review of the asbestos EA is to
estimate the value of the fixed capital stock for different supply segments in the market to
proxy for the steps in the supply function.

The implicit assumption with the step supply function is that each producer has a
supply limit due to capacity constraints. While the absolute capacity constraints provide some
notion of the short-run rigidities that are elemental to an analysis of economic impacts, the
constraints are rather rigid. Suppliers, even in the short run, usually have enough flexibility to
modify production levels at least somewhat, hence the conceptual advantages of some sort of
upward price responsiveness in the short run. Nonetheless, as a first approximation, the step
supply function provides a substantial improvement to the horizontal aggregate supply
function (i.e., a one-step/infinite-width supply function) by at least accounting for cost

5-29


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

differences across suppliers, which further enables a better characterization of impacts across
suppliers.

An alternative, less elaborate approach to the step supply function of Figure 5-9 may
be employed when data are not available to fully characterize this function. The alternative
approach implicitly utilizes the step supply framework; but in the absence of actual data to
parameterize the function, the analyst employs knowledge of the subject industry, the
applicability of controls across the affected population, and economic theory to develop
sensitivity scenarios that qualitatively address potential economic impacts of a proposed
regulatory action. With a step supply function, the marginal (highest cost) producer
determines the market price. Therefore, the compliance costs of the marginal supplier
determine the increase in market price. If the marginal producer is expected to incur a higher
level of compliance cost than the inframarginal producers, this suggests that producers, in
aggregate, can more than pass on regulatory costs to consumers. Here, the expected price
increase is higher than the per-unit compliance costs of inframarginal producers so these
producers are expected to gain as a result of the regulatory action at the expense of
consumers paying higher prices. Alternatively, if the marginal producer is expected to incur a
lower relative level of compliance costs, then the regulatory burden is likely to fall more
heavily on inframarginal producers as the expected price increase is lower than their per-unit
compliance costs. This approach allows the analyst to inform the regulatory development
process in cases with severe lack of data or time and resources.

Incorporating Import Supply. The discussion above focuses on domestic sources of
supply for the affect product(s). However, if foreign imports account for a significant share of
U.S. apparent consumption of the regulated product, then the ISEG analyst should attempt to
incorporate them into the economic model. In this case, the preferred approach is to define
the relevant markets as the United States and to include imports as a source of supply that is
added to and competes with domestic sources of supply. In addition to providing insights on
the regulatory effect on foreign competition, accounting for foreign imports will allow the
market model to better measure the impacts on domestic suppliers in aggregate and their
distribution across individual producers or producing segments. For example, if the supply
curve for imports is perfectly elastic (i.e., a horizontal foreign import supply curve), then the
U.S. market price is fixed at the world market price and will not change in response to the
proposed regulatory action. This occurs because foreign imports will totally offset any
reductions in domestic production as they are deemed perfect substitutes and unconstrained in

5-30


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

terms of availability. Under this scenario, domestic producers would have to absorb the entire
regulatory cost burden and be more likely to close. A more plausible scenario is one with an
upward-sloping supply curve for imports that reflects the ability of these sources to partially
offset reductions in domestic production with increases in the U.S. market price.

This foreign source of supply is typically characterized using a prototype supply
function with parameter inputs as described above for domestic suppliers. Therefore, the
analyst must determine the elasticity of the import supply function through econometric
estimation or appropriate literature estimates. The difficulty in econometrically estimating
import and/or export elasticities from the international trade data has long been recognized.
Orcutt (1950) demonstrated that elasticity estimates derived from regressions of a country's
import (export) quantity on historical prices understate the true price responsiveness of
imports and exports, typically by a substantial magnitude. Part of the difficulty derives from
the identification problem in estimating a supply/demand system, which is more pronounced
given the difficulty in procuring measures of exogenous demand and supply factors for foreign
consumers and producers. However, Orcutt demonstrates how to derive the total elasticity of
imports/exports, which accounts for the effect of the change in price on all (foreign and
domestic) producing and consuming parties. In the absence of literature estimates of foreign
trade elasticities, the ISEG analyst can employ this type of method to numerically compute the
elasticities of import supply (export demand) as done for the EIA conducted in support of the
Pulp and Paper Cluster Rule.

Regulation-Induced Shift in Supply Functions. The starting point for assessing the
market impacts of a regulatory action is to incorporate the regulatory compliance costs into
the production decision of affected producers. In other words, the focus here is to quantify
the shift in the supply function caused by the regulation. An upward shift in the supply
function represents the additional cost per unit of producing output because of compliance
activities on a "before-tax" basis.16 In most analyses, this shift is quantified by taking the total
annual compliance cost estimate and dividing it by baseline output quantity and computing the
average cost per unit of output. Then, the supply function is shifted up by that amount. In

16Some economic analyses adjust the compliance costs to account for implications of the U.S. tax code on the
regulatory burden (e.g., depreciation allowances). However, the extent to which these tax-related outcomes
influence the behavior of affected producers is considered to be very small and therefore not typically
included in the "supply shift." The after tax consequences seem to have a much greater influence on the
ultimate distribution of the regulatory burden across stakeholders as producers attempt to pass along
portions of their burden to U.S. Treasury or taxpayers through the tax code. The analysis of these types of
impacts are more appropriately addressed in a complementary financial analysis.

5-31


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

essence, computing the supply shift this way treats compliance costs as the conceptual
equivalent of a unit tax on output, and the computation of consumer and producer welfare
effects follows the classical treatment of tax burden distribution in the public finance literature
(e.g., Harberger, 1974).17

Because compliance costs are typically divided into capital and operating costs, the
parallel shift illustrated previously (e.g., Figures 5-1 and 5-2) implies that both capital and
operating costs vary with output levels. At least in the case of capital, this raises some
questions. In the long run, all inputs (and their costs) can be expected to vary with output.
But short(er)-run analysis typically holds some capital factors fixed. For instance, to the
extent that a market supply function is tied to existing facilities, there is an element of fixed
capital. As indicated above, the current market supply function might reflect these fixed
factors with an upward slope or rising steps. Figure 5-10(a) provides the case with an
upward-sloping supply curve. In this case, the MC curve will only be affected, or shift
upwards, by the per-unit variable compliance costs (Cx), while the ATAC curve will shift up
by the per-unit total compliance costs (C2). Thus, the variable costs will directly affect the
production decision (optimal output rate), and the fixed costs will affect the operating
decision by establishing a new higher reservation price for the firm (i.e., Pm ). However, with
regard to the capital costs of compliance, the argument can be made that these expenditures
have not yet been made; therefore, their scale could, at least in principle, be thought to vary
with the level of output. Thus, the imposition of capital costs as part of a parallel shift may
not distort the situation too significantly. In general, the degree to which it is appropriate to
include capital costs of compliance should be evaluated on a case-by-case basis and may be
the subject of sensitivity analysis.

Under the special case of a step supply function, each step will rise by the amount of
that segment's per-unit total compliance costs, as indicated in Figure 5-10(b). As shown, in
this case, the MC curve will shift by the per-unit total compliance costs (C) to allow the new
higher reservation price for the firm to appropriately reflect the fixed costs of compliance in
the operating decision. This could cause a re-ordering of the steps to construct the market
supply function because the compliance costs may cause some supply segments with lower

"There may be some conceptual shortcomings to treating pollution control as equivalent to an output tax. For
example, the regulations may cause firms to alter their production processes to reduce the cost of
compliance, in which case the output tax equivalent, computed with ex ante cost estimates may overstate
the true size of the supply shift. As a practical matter though the output tax approach dominates current
practice.

5-32


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

$/q

pm'

(a) Upward-sloping supply function

$/q

pm'

(b) Inverted L-shaped supply function

Figure 5-10. Regulation-Induced Cost Shifts by Supply Characterization

5-33


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

costs than other segments without the regulation to be higher cost than those same segments
with the regulation. If a supply segment gets pushed to the point that it is entirely above the
demand curve, then the market price will be below that segment's threshold price and it will
not willingly supply the market. In those cases, the model predicts that the supply segment in
question will exit the market in response to the regulation.

5.3.3.2 Demand Characterization and Responses

The demand function relates the quantity demanded of a particular commodity to its
price and other factors, such as income and the price of substitutes. The factors other than the
product's price are typically held constant in regulatory analysis, unless, for example, specific
evidence is given that the market price of substitutes is substantially affected by the regulation.
In that case, multiple market analysis or general equilibrium analysis may be necessary. But
that is the exception rather than the rule. Therefore, the focus of the demand function
specification is to establish the quantitative relationship between price and quantity demanded
in the regulated market.

There are three options for demand function specification:

•	econometric estimation,

•	prototype demand function with parameter inputs, and

•	step demand function.

The first option, econometric estimation, uses econometric methods applied to data on
demand quantities, price, and the other theoretically relevant variables. For information on
specific methods for estimating demand systems, refer to any one of a number of econometric
textbooks' specific treatment of demand systems (e.g., Intriligator, 1978; Berndt, 1991) or
simultaneous estimation of supply and demand systems (see Kennedy [1994] for an overview).
Econometric estimation, if done correctly, has the advantage of tying together economic
theory and data to produce a consistent and empirically defensible characterization of the
demand function, which can then be used to simulate market outcomes and welfare effects of
regulatory actions, as described above. Econometric estimation, however, is often hindered
by practical concerns such as the absence of high quality data to support estimation or limited
project resources. When this is the case, alternative approaches must be considered.

5-34


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

The first alternative to direct econometric estimation considered here is the
specification of a general form for the demand function. As shown in Figure 5-11, the general
form of the demand function may be linear or have constant elasticity. Again, the
Cobb-Douglass form provides an example (i.e., constant elasticity form):

where QD is the demand quantity, P is the price, E is the price elasticity, and a is a parameter
that represents the scale of the relationship between quantity and price. The scale parameter,
a, can be "backsolved" given baseline values of QD, P, and E. Or the analysis can be
performed to simply solve for changes in the quantity demanded as a function of changes in
price as follows:

and the proportional changes can be calibrated to baseline values to compute absolute
measures of price, quantity, and welfare effects.

QD = aPE

(5.2)

(AQ d/Q d)=E(AP/P)

(5.3)

D

D

a) Linear
Figure 5-11. Demand Curves

b) Constant Elasticity

5-35


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

The price elasticity, E, can be derived from previous econometric estimates in the
literature. If no previous studies have been conducted for the market in question, then
estimates from similar markets may be appropriate. The more uncertainty surrounding the
true value of the demand elasticity, the more the analyst may want to rely on sensitivity
analysis to capture the relevant range of parameter values. Figure 5-12 provides an example
from an economic analysis of air pollution regulations for agricultural chemicals in which
model results are evaluated for demand elasticities in the range found in the literature
(Research Triangle Institute, 1997). More information on how to use sensitivity analysis to
reflect underlying parameter uncertainty is presented in Section 8.

Incorporating Export Demand. The discussion above focuses on domestic sources of
demand for the affect product(s). However, if foreign exports account for a significant share
of U.S. domestic production of the regulated product, then the ISEG analyst should attempt
to incorporate them into the economic model. In this case, the preferred approach is to define
the relevant markets as the United States and to include exports as a source of demand that is
added to domestic demand. In addition to providing insights on the regulatory effect on

Elasticity of Demand

-0.10	-0.72	-1.53	-2.35	-3.00

Figure 5-12. Sensitivity of Changes in Producer and Consumer Surplus to the Elasticity
of Demand (Elasticity of Supply = 1.0)

5-36


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

foreign competition, accounting for foreign exports will allow the market model to better
measure the impacts on market price and aggregate demand and their incidence across
domestic and foreign consumers. This foreign source of demand is typically characterized
using a prototype demand function with parameter inputs as described above for domestic
demanders. Therefore, the analyst must determine the elasticity of the export demand
function through methods similar to those discussed above for incorporating import supply.

5.3.3.3 Determine With-Regulation Equilibrium

Producers' and consumers' responses and market adjustments can be conceptualized
as an interactive feedback process. Facilities face increased production costs due to
compliance, which causes facility-specific production responses, the cumulative effect of
which leads to a change in the market price that all producers (affected and unaffected) and
consumers face, which leads to further responses by producers (affected and unaffected) as
well as consumers and thus new market prices, and so on. The new equilibrium after
imposition of the regulatory action requires total market supply equals total market demand,
that is,

Qs = QD, for all product markets.

Given the producer and consumer behavioral response functions, this new equilibrium may be
solved simultaneously using analytical solution mechanisms18 or iteratively using numerical
solution mechanisms.19 These solution mechanisms allow for computation of a counterfactual
or with-regulation equilibrium that can be compared with the baseline scenario to derive the
economic impacts of a regulatory action as discussed in the next section.

5.4 Economic Impact Results

This section summarizes the measures of economic impacts that result from the
modeling approach described above. The model results are summarized below as
market-level, facility- or industry-level, company-level, and community-level impacts, as well
as the social costs impacts due to implementation of a proposed regulatory action. The
sample results tables in this section are taken from the EIA conducted in support of the

18This solution mechanism operates in proportional changes and employs the matrix algebra solution of the
behavioral equations.

19This solution mechanism operates in total changes and employs a process of tatonnement, whereby prices
approach equilibrium through successive correction modeled as a Walrasian auctioneer.

5-37


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Polymers and Resins III NESHAP. Although the EIA results presented here are not large in
magnitude, these tables provide good illustrations of the broad array of impact measures that
can result from this modeling approach.

5.4.1	Market-Level Results

Table 5-3 provides an example of the market-level impacts of a proposed regulatory
action. These impacts include the market adjustments in price and quantity for affected
products, as well as the changes in foreign trade (if applicable). The increased cost of
controlling air emissions from existing affected sources is shown to reduce their production,
which subsequently causes price and output changes in each market. As expected, the
proposed regulation is projected to increase the prices and reduce market output. In this case,
the reduction in market quantities of each product is the net effect of reductions in domestic
production and increases in foreign imports. Furthermore, as shown in Table 5-3, the
reduction in domestic production is the net of changes at affected producers (reductions) and
unaffected producers (increases). Thus, the market-based approach allows the analyst to
evaluate the distributional impacts within the U.S. industry and across U.S. versus foreign
producers.

5.4.2	Industry-Level Results

Table 5-4 provides an example of the industry-level impacts associated with a
proposed regulation. Industry-level impacts include an evaluation of the aggregate changes in
revenue, costs, and operating profits across individual producers; facility and product-line
closures; and the change in employment attributable to projected closures and changes
(increases/decreases) in production from directly and indirectly affected facilities. The
industry revenues and costs change as market prices and individual facility production levels
adjust to the imposition of the regulation. The post-regulatory compliance costs account for
market adjustments and, thus, will be less than the initial engineering estimate of compliance
costs due to reductions in production and/or market exits.

Based on projected individual and market responses, the economic analysis estimates
changes in industry profits. The ultimate impact of the regulation on industry profits will
depend on the incidence of compliance costs and the nature of demand and supply curves. In
fact, under certain circumstances, the regulation may cause aggregate industry profits to
increase. Assuming that demand is not perfectly inelastic, if the supply curve were to shift
upward in a parallel manner, then the effect on producer surplus, or profits, would be

5-38


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

Table 5-3. Summary of Market-Level Impacts of the Proposed Polymers and Resins III
NESHAP: 1991

With Changes from Baseline
Baseline Regulation Absolute Percent

Amino resins

Market price ($/lb)

$0.26

$0.26

$0.00

0.08%

Market output (million lbs/yr)

1,704.0

1,703.2

-0.84

-0.05%

Domestic production

1,679.0

1,678.1

-0.86

-0.05%

Affected® producers

1,091.8

1,090.5

-1.30

-0.12%

Unaffected producers

587.2

587.6

0.45

0.08%

Exports

50.7

50.7

-0.02

-0.05%

Imports

25.0

25.0

0.02

0.08%

lenolic resins









Market price ($/lb)

$0.49

$0.49

$0.00

0.07%

Market output (million lbs/yr)

2,694.0

2,693.6

-0.41

-0.02%

Domestic production

2,658.0

2,657.6

-0.44

-0.02%

Affected® producers

2,479.3

2,478.8

-0.56

-0.02%

Unaffected producers

178.7

178.8

0.12

0.07%

Exports

92.7

92.7

-0.01

-0.02%

Imports

36.0

36.0

0.02

0.07%

a Reflects aggregate resin production volumes from 40 major source manufacturing facilities affected by the
proposed NESHAP.

negative. For this type of shift, the incidence of compliance costs across affected producers is
independent of their baseline production costs. In some cases, however, the compliance costs
may be higher for those producers that have the highest baseline production costs. Under this
scenario, the supply curve movement will be a combined pivotal and parallel shift as shown in
Figure 5-13. As shown by Miller, Rosenblatt, and Hushak (1988), depending on the value of
the slope and intercept of the supply and demand curves, the joint effect of this type of shift
may cause an overall increase in producer surplus rather than the expected decrease resulting
from the parallel shift alone. In an extreme case, the new market price could be solely

5-39


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Table 5-4. Summary of National-Level Industry Impacts of the Proposed Polymers and
Resins III NESHAP: 1991





With

Changes from Baseline



Baseline

Regulation

Absolute

Percent

Resin revenues ($ million/yr)

$1,739.0

$1,739.8

$0.80

0.05%

Costs ($ million/yr)

$897.9

$899.9

$2.08

0.23%

Post-regulatory

$0.0

$2.5

$2.51

NA

Resin production

$897.9

$897.4

-$0.43

-0.05%

Operating profits ($ million/yr)

$841.1

$839.8

-$1.28

-0.15%

Operating product lines (#)

NA

NA

-2

NA

Employment loss (FTEs)

NA

NA

-33

NA

NA = not available
FTEs = Full-time equivalents

Figure 5-13. Market Outcomes with Nonparallel Supply Shift

5-40


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

determined by the increased costs of the marginal producer who would account for the entire
reduction in output and profits with all inframarginal producers gaining profits at its expense.

As shown in Table 5-4, the projected reduction in profits is less than the regulatory
costs they incur because producers reduce their production, resulting in higher market prices
for each resin, which effectively shifts a portion of the regulatory burden onto consumers.
Furthermore, the aggregate increase in industry profits is a result of the net change in profits
at affected and unaffected U.S. producers. Table 5-5 provides results on distributional
impacts of the rule within the industry that are not apparent from the aggregate industry-level
impacts shown in Table 5-4. As discussed previously, in a market context, producers are able
to adjust their production levels in response to the increase in costs as well as the projected
increase in market prices. As shown in Table 5-5, affected resin producers are projected to
incur a decrease in operating profits, while unaffected resin producers are expected to incur
an increase in operating profits.

The economic analysis may also project closures of facilities or product lines
associated with imposition of the regulatory action. In response to added costs of compliance,
it could be that the optimal choice for a facility is to shutdown particular product lines,
processes, or the entire operation altogether. The sufficient condition for production at a
facility or production unit is defined as nonnegative net profits, that is,

Profits = TR - TC > 0

where total revenue (TR) is the sum of product revenue at the facility, and total cost (TC) is
the sum of total variable production costs and total avoidable fixed costs. This closure
decision does not typically include an annualized value for the liquidation opportunity cost,
which is equivalent to assuming that the opportunity cost of fixed assets is offset by costs of
closing the facility. It is important to point out that the estimates of facility and product-line
closures are sensitive to the accuracy of the baseline characterization of these entities (e.g.,
prices received for manufactured products, costs of production) and the estimation of their
costs of complying with the proposed regulatory action.

5-41


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Table 5-5. Distribution of Industry-Level Impacts of Proposed NESHAP by Affected
and Unaffected Producers: 1991

With Changes From Baseline
Baseline Regulation Absolute Percent

Affected® producers

Resin revenues ($ million/yr)

$1,498.8

$1,499.2

$0.44

0.03%

Costs ($ million/yr)

$785.0

$786.9

$1.90

0.24%

Post-regulatory

$0.0

$2.5

$2.51

NA

Resin production

$785.0

$784.4

-$0.61

-0.08%

Operating profits ($ million/yr)

$713.7

$712.3

-$1.46

-0.20%

Operating product lines (#)

59

57

-2

-3.39%

Employment loss (FTEs)

2,437

2,404

-33

-1.36%

affected producers









Resin revenues ($ million/yr)

$240.2

$240.6

$0.33

0.15%

Costs ($ million/yr)

$112.8

$113.0

$0.18

0.16%

Post-regulatory

$0.0

$0.0

NA

NA

Resin production

$112.8

$113.0

$0.18

0.16%

Operating profits ($ million/yr)

$127.4

$127.6

$0.18

0.14%

Operating product lines (#)

NA

NA

NA

NA

Employment loss (FTEs)

NA

NA

NA

NA

a Reflects aggregate impacts for the 40 major source manufacturing facilities affected by the proposed
NESHAP.

Furthermore, the regulatory action may displace workers from jobs through its impacts
on levels of production. The methodology employed to estimate the number of displaced
workers depends on the methodology used to project output effects (individual facility or
aggregate market response). If facility output decisions are modeled, then changes in
employment at facilities that continue to operate after regulation are estimated by multiplying

5-42


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

a facility-specific ratio of production workers per output (i.e., e) by the projected change in
the facility's production (i.e., Aq). If the facility ceases to operate, then the change in
employment at the mill equals total employment, both production and nonproduction workers
(i.e., E). Thus, the estimate of the change in employment for the entire industry can be
obtained by adding the sum of the employment changes across all facilities that continue to
operate and the sum of total employment across all facilities that close. This produces a net
estimate that aggregates the job losses at facilities that close or reduce production and job
gains at facilities that increase production. Therefore, to estimate only employee
displacement, or job losses, the analyst may sum the projected change in employment for
those facilities that close or reduce their production level. Alternatively, if only market
responses are modeled, then only a net measure of employment change may be computed by
multiplying an industry-specific ratio of employment per output by the projected change in
aggregate industry production.

5.4.3 Company-Level Impacts

A regulatory action to reduce air emissions from particular facilities will potentially
affect the business entities that own the regulated facilities. Companies or individuals that
own the facilities are legal business entities that have the capacity to conduct business
transactions and make business decisions that affect the operations at the facility. The legal
and financial responsibility for compliance with a regulatory action rests with these owners
who must ultimately bear the financial consequences of their decisions. The owners' response
options to a proposed regulatory action potentially include the following:20

•	implement the cost-minimizing compliance option and continue to operate the
facility,

•	close the facility voluntarily, or

•	close the facility involuntarily.

Owners are assumed to pursue the course of action that maximizes the value of the firm,
subject, of course, to uncertainties about actual costs of compliance and the behavior of other
companies. The market approach presented in this section addresses the first two response

20Firms also face financial choices regarding how to fund their compliance responses: diverting dividends from
investors (i.e., out of profits), internal equity (i.e., issuing new stock), or external equity (i.e., borrowing).
Although these financial decisions are not addressed in conducting the market-based approach, these
decisions will influence the real resource burden to the firm and society.

5-43


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

options listed above. As mentioned in the introduction to Section 5, the facility and market
impacts should feed into the financial analysis to assess the financial viability of the owning
companies (i.e., company-level impacts). In other words, the analyst must identify which
companies are likely to have problems meeting their debt obligations in the face of regulation
and be required to liquidate facility assets under option three above. In addition, this type of
analysis addresses distributional issues across these companies with special concern for
disparate impacts on small businesses.

The financial analysis evaluates the change in firm health by computing the with-
regulation financial ratios of potentially affected firms and comparing them to the
corresponding baseline ratios or industry-specific standards. These financial ratios may
include indicators of liquidity, asset management, debt management, and profitability.

Although a variety of possible financial ratios provide individual indicators of a firm's health,
they most often do not give the same signals. Therefore, the company-level analysis should
focus only on changes in key measures of profitability, that is,

•	return on sales, which is computed as net income divided by sales;

•	return on assets, which is computed as net income divided by total assets; and

•	return on equity, which is computed as net income divided by owner's equity, or
net worth.

As a result of a proposed regulation, owners will potentially experience changes in profits
associated with changes in the costs and revenues of their manufacturing operations. Net
changes in profitability may be derived by summing facility cost and revenue changes across
all facilities owned by each affected company. The net impact on a company's profitability
may be negative (i.e., cost increases exceed revenue increases) or positive (i.e., revenue
increases exceed cost increases). In most cases, there is little reason to go beyond the
assessment of changes in profitability. Although issues of capital availability are important to
address, especially in regard to small businesses, they are often difficult to assess accurately
and may provide little more information beyond the assessment of firm profitability.

5.4.4 Community-Level Impacts

Based on the facility- and industry-level impacts, community or region-specific impacts
of a proposed regulatory action can be computed for employment and tax revenues. Changes
in employment and tax revenues are linked to the projected change in production and profits

5-44


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

at affected and unaffected producers located in the geographic areas of interest (i.e., counties,
states, or regions). Computing the community impacts involves aggregating the
facility-specific changes for each measure of interest.

5.4.5 Social Costs of the Regulation

As stipulated in E.O. 12866, when a proposed regulatory action is deemed
"significant," an estimate of a regulation's social cost is compared with an estimate of social
benefits to determine whether the benefits justify the costs. Toward that end, the social cost
of a regulation should represent its opportunity cost (OMB, 1996, p. 32), which is the value
of the goods and services that society foregoes to allocate resources to the pollution control
activity.

The analyst considers three types of social cost in conducting EIAs:

•	the costs of actions taken to comply with the regulation,

•	the costs of administering and enforcing the regulation, and

•	the costs associated with economic impacts.

The first category reflects the opportunity cost of the resources applied to compliance
activities. When regulation takes the form of mandated private actions, the opportunity cost
of these actions ideally is captured in measures of producer and consumer surplus from the
markets affected by the regulation. These surplus measures can be directly computed from
the market-based approach presented in this section and typically account for the majority of
the total cost of a regulatory action. Thus, this estimate is most often presented in the EIA as
the social cost of regulation.21'22 The methodology for computing these measures is presented
below. When lack of market data and model parameters impedes the computation of

21 See Section 8 for a detailed discussion of a more comprehensive estimate of social cost for comparison with
social benefits that accounts for the effects of discounting at different rate (i.e., private versus social
discount rates).

22It is important to point out that the baseline conditions (excess capacity), model parameters (supply and
demand elasticities), and market structure will influence the magnitude and distribution of these surplus-
based measures. The reader is referred to the EIAs conducted for pharmaceuticals (monopoly) and
Portland cement (oligopoly) for illustrations of the effects of imperfectly competitive market structures on
these estimates.

5-45


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

producer and consumer surplus measures, engineering or accounting methods must be used to
approximate social costs.

However, other components of social cost may not be fully accounted for in the
compliance cost estimates and, thus, not reflected in the partial equilibrium framework. These
other components of social costs include government monitoring and enforcement costs and
the costs associated with economic impacts such as involuntary unemployment, plant closings,
and changes in innovation. In these cases, other valuation approaches must be used to
separately examine and measure these other cost components.

5.4.5.1 Producer and Consumer Surplus Measures

The value of a regulatory action is traditionally measured by the change in economic
welfare that it generates. Welfare impacts resulting from a proposed regulatory action on the
U.S. society will extend to the many consumers and producers of affected commodities.
Consumers will experience welfare impacts due to the adjustments in market prices and
consumption levels that result from imposition of the regulation. Producer welfare impacts
result from the changes in product revenues to all producers associated with the imposition of
the rule and the corresponding changes in production and market prices. Based on applied
welfare economics principles, Table 5-6 presents an example of the estimates of the social
costs and their distribution by stakeholder from the EIA conducted in support of the Polymers
and Resins III NESHAP.

The economic welfare implications of the market price and output changes associated
with a proposed regulatory action can be examined using changes in the net benefits of
consumers and producers. Figure 5-14 depicts this approach to estimating social costs by first
measuring the change in consumer surplus and then the change in producer surplus. In
essence, the demand and supply curves previously described as predictive devices are now
being used as a valuation tool. This method of estimating the social costs of the regulation
decomposes society into consumers and producers. In a market environment, consumers and
producers of the good or service derive welfare from a market transaction. The difference
between the maximum price consumers are willing to pay for a good and the price they
actually pay is referred to as "consumer surplus." Consumer surplus is measured as the area
under the demand curve and above the price of the product. Similarly, the difference between
the minimum price producers are willing to accept for a good and the price they actually
receive is referred to as "producer surplus." Producer surplus is measured as the area above

5-46


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

Table 5-6. Distribution of Social Costs Associated with the Proposed Polymers and
Resins III NESHAP: 1991



Change in Value

Stakeholder

($ million)

Consumer surplus, total

-$1,250

Amino resin consumers

-$0,336

Phenolic resin consumers

-$0,914

Producer surplus, total

-$1,276

Domestic producers

-$1,281

Affected®

-$1,458

Unaffected

$0,177

Foreign producers

$0,005

Social costs of regulation

-$2,527

a	Reflects aggregate change in profits from the 40 major source manufacturing facilities affected by the

proposed NESHAP.

the supply curve below the price of the product. These areas can be thought of as consumers'
net benefits of consumption and producers' net benefits of production, respectively.

In Figure 5-14, baseline equilibrium occurs at the intersection of the demand curve, D,
and supply curve, S. Price is P, with quantity Q,. The increased cost of production with the
regulation will cause the market supply curve to shift upward to S\ The new equilibrium price
of the product is P2. With a higher price for the product there is less consumer welfare, all
else being unchanged. In Figure 5-14(a), area A represents the dollar value of the annual net
loss in consumers' benefits with the increased price. The rectangular portion represents the
loss in consumer surplus on the quantity still consumed, Q2, while the triangular area
represents the foregone surplus resulting from the reduced quantity consumed, Qj-Q2-

In addition to the changes in consumers' welfare, there are also changes in producers'
welfare with the regulatory action. With the increase in market price, producers receive
higher revenues on the quantity still purchased, Q2. In Figure 5-14(b), area B represents the

5-47


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

(a) Change in Consumer Surplus with Regulation

(b) Change in Producer Surplus with Regulation

(c) Net Change in Economic Welfare with Regulation

Figure 5-14. Economic Welfare Changes with Regulation: Consumer and Producer
Surplus

5-48


-------
Section 5 — EIA Analytical Framework and Operational Issues

increase in revenues due to this increase in price. The difference in the area under the supply
curve up to the original market price, area C, measures the loss in producers surplus, which
includes the loss associated with the quantity no longer produced. The net change in
producers' welfare is represented by area B-C.

The change in economic welfare attributable to the compliance costs of the regulations
is the sum of consumer and producer surplus changes, that is, - (A) + (B-C). Figure 5-14(c)
shows the net (negative) change in economic welfare associated with the regulation as area D.
However, it is important to reemphasize that this measure does not include the benefits that
occur outside the market, that is, the value of the reduced levels of air pollution with the
regulations. Including this benefit may reduce the net cost of the regulation or even make it
positive; that is, total benefits, which are private market benefits as estimated above plus the
benefits in the quality of the environment, may exceed total costs.

5.4.5.2 Other Elements of Social Costs

Administrative and enforcement activities involve real resource expenditures that could
be spent on the provision of other goods and services thereby imposing social opportunity
costs that must be accounted for in the EA.23 Administration and enforcement costs are borne
by the taxpayers who fund regulatory government agencies such as EPA and state, tribal, or
local agencies that enforce environmental regulations. Once rules are put in place, resources
must be expended to administer the regulation and ensure compliance. The types of costs to
consider are staffing, materials, and office rental costs (excluding those associated with rule
development). Typically, these costs do not affect market outcomes and are appropriately
added to the surplus-based estimates from above to gain a more complete estimate of social
costs.

Government administrative and enforcement costs are usually estimated using
straightforward methods based on added administrative activities and their associated costs.
Information on resource requirements (e.g., full-time equivalent staff needs) and the cost (e.g.,
salary and fringe) can be obtained directly from enforcement agencies. The difficulty is in
determining the extent to which a new regulation incrementally raises these costs. For
example, enforcement agencies exist with or without the regulation. Rather than increase the
size of the enforcement agency, the new regulation may just spread the responsibilities over

23These real resource costs are distinguished from tax transfers to or from the government, which have no net
effect on social costs.

5-49


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

the existing staff. Assuming that the staff is not currently being underutilized, this may just
reduce the frequency of enforcement activity for each regulation under the agency's purview.

Finally, the proposed regulatory action might generate economic impacts, the full
social costs of which are not captured in the measures of compliance, administration, and
enforcement costs. An example may be transitional costs associated with unemployment,24
mandated obsolescence of otherwise useful capital, or reductions in long-run economic
efficiency due to reduced innovation. The costs of these impacts are often difficult to quantify
and are usually addressed in separate impact analyses to provide decisionmakers with a more
detailed and richer characterization of the consequences of a particular regulatory action.
These separate impact analyses are described in more detail in Section 8.

24Worker displacement costs have traditionally not been measured in EIAs conducted by ISEG analysts. The
assumption has usually been made that workers costlessly move to new jobs of equal productivity and
earnings, despite numerous studies that show costs borne by displaced workers are significant (see Flaim,
1984; Hamermesh, 1989; Maxwell, 1989; and Anderson and Chandran, 1987). Building on the work by
Adams (1985) and Topel (1984), Anderson and Chandran (1987) constructed incremental willingness-to-
pay (WTP) measures for job dislocations in a hedonic wage framework that may be employed to estimate
worker dislocation costs.

5-50


-------
Section 6 — Impact Analyses

SECTION 6
IMPACT ANALYSES

Impact analysis is a general term used to describe various economic analyses that are
supplemental to the estimates of total benefits and costs. These analyses go beyond a simple
benefit-cost analysis to examine various aspects of the composition of benefits and costs. The
impact analyses required by EO and statute were introduced in Section 2 of this manual.

Three statutes specifically require an analysis of regulatory impacts:

•	UMRA requires an analysis of intergovernmental impacts.

•	RFA, as amended by SBREFA, requires an analysis of impacts on small entities.1

•	PRA, as amended, requires an analysis of recordkeeping and reporting impacts.

The requirements imposed by each of these statutes are described in detail in Sections 6.1
through 6.3. In addition, the Environmental Justice and Children's Health EOs require each
Federal agency to assess the impacts of its regulations on minority and low-income
populations and on children, respectively. These and other distribution effects are discussed in
Section 8.4. Special emphasis is given in this section to those distribution effects mentioned in
these EOs and in EO 12866 (Regulatory Planning and Review). The last subsection of this
section briefly identifies other structural impacts addressed in economic analyses of
regulations.

6.1 The Unfunded Mandates Reform Act (UMRA)

UMRA requires that Federal agencies assess the effects of Federal regulations on
State, local, and tribal governments and the private sector. In particular, UMRA requires that
agencies prepare a written statement to accompany any rulemaking that "includes any Federal

'Section l(b)(l 1) of EO 12866 also requires that agencies tailor their regulations to impose the least burden on
small businesses, small communities, and government entities, thereby implicitly requiring an analysis of
the impacts imposed on these specific groups of entities.

6-1


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

mandate that may result in the expenditure by State, local, and tribal governments, in the
aggregate, or by the private sector, of $100,000,000 or more (annually adjusted for inflation)
in any one year" (Section 202(a)). The term "Federal mandate" means a Federal
intergovernmental mandate or a Federal private-sector mandate. These terms are precisely
defined in the statute as follows:

'Federal intergovernmental mandate' means (A) any provision
in legislation, statute, or regulation that (i) would impose an
enforceable duty upon State, local, or tribal governments,
except (I) a condition of Federal assistance; or (II) a duty
arising from participation in a voluntary Federal program... (B)
any provision in legislation, statute, or regulation that relates to
a then-existing Federal program under which $500,000,000 or
more is provided annually to State, local, and tribal
governments under entitlement authority, if the provision (i)(I)
would increase the stringency of conditions of assistance to
State, local, or tribal governments under the program; or (II)
would place caps upon, or otherwise decrease, the Federal
Government's responsibility to provide funding to State, local,
or tribal governments under the program; and (ii) the State,
local, or tribal governments that participate in the Federal
program lack authority under that program to amend their
financial or programmatic responsibilities to continue providing
required services that are affected by the legislation, statute, or
regulation.

'Federal private sector mandate' means any provision in
legislation, statute, or regulation that (A) would impose an
enforceable duty upon the private sector except (i) a condition
of Federal assistance; or (ii) a duty arising from participation in
a voluntary Federal program; or (B) would reduce or eliminate
the amount of authorization of appropriations for Federal
financial assistance that will be provided to the private sector
for the purposes of ensuring compliance with such duty
(Section 421).

The written statement must

•	identify the statutory authority under which the rule is to be promulgated;

•	assess the benefits and costs of the rule; and

6-2


-------
Section 6 — Impact Analyses

•	describe the Agency's consultation with State, local, and tribal government
officials during the development of the rule.

If a written statement is prepared for a proposed rule, then the final rule must also include a
written statement, updated to reflect any changes in analysis or intergovernmental consultation
that has occurred since the proposal stage. The written statement should be prepared as a
joint effort between the ISEG analyst and the workgroup.

The statute provides specific directions regarding the contents of the benefit-cost
analysis to be included in the written statement. In particular, UMRA requires that the
analysis

•	analyze the extent to which costs incurred by State, local, and tribal governments
can be paid with Federal financial assistance;

•	assess the extent to which Federal resources are available to carry out the Federal
mandate;

•	estimate future compliance costs;

•	identify and analyze any disproportionate budgetary effect of the Federal mandate
on a particular region of the country; a particular State, local, or tribal government;
or a particular segment of the private sector;

•	assess the effects of the rule on the national economy, including productivity,
economic growth, employment and job creation, and international competitiveness;
and

•	identify and analyze a reasonable number of regulatory alternatives.

While the information developed to meet the EA requirements of EO 12866 will
generally satisfy the analytical requirements outlined above, three basic requirements unique to
UMRA need to be met independently of any EA conducted under another authority:

•	ISEG analysts will need to conduct a preliminary expenditure assessment to
determine whether the rule is likely to impose a mandate of more than $100 million
in any one year. EPA guidance recommends that this preliminary assessment be
conducted for any rule having consequences for non-Federal governments or the
private sector. This preliminary assessment differs somewhat from an assessment
conducted to determine whether a rule is economically significant under

EO 12866. An economically significant regulation as defined by EO 12866 is any
rule likely to have an annual impact of $100 million or more. In contrast, the

6-3


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

standard expressed in UMRA requires an analysis of direct expenditures by non-
Federal governments or the private sector. The purpose of the expenditure
assessment is, therefore, to determine whether direct expenditures by either non-
Federal levels of government or the private sector are likely to exceed $100 million
in any one year.2

•	UMRA requires an analysis of possible Federal assistance to State, local, and tribal
governments on which the mandate is imposed. This requirement is unique to
UMRA and involves Federal budgetary considerations not usually addressed in an
economic analysis prepared under EO 12866.

•	UMRA specifically requires an analysis of the distribution of impacts across
regions of the country, different levels or types of governments, and various
sectors of the economy. In contrast, most analyses prepared under EO 12866
assess the impact of the rule on the nation as a whole, rather than on a region-by-
region or sector-by-sector basis.

For further guidance on conducting expenditure assessments and impact analyses
under UMRA, analysts are referred to the Agency's Unfunded Mandates Guidance (EPA,
1995b).

6.2 The Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA) and Small Business Regulatory

Enforcement Fairness Act (SBREFA)

The RFA, as amended by SBREFA of 1996, requires Federal regulatory agencies to
determine whether a proposed or final regulation will have a significant impact on a substantial
number of small entities.3 In particular, the RFA requires that an agency prepare an IRFA
for any proposed rule and an FRF A for any final rule that is subject to notice-and-comment
rulemaking under the Administrative Procedures Act (APA) unless the agency head certifies

2The $100 million expenditure test must be applied to the governments and the private sector separately. For
example, if a rule requires governments to spend $75 million and the private sector to spend $75 million in
a given year, then a written statement would not be required under UMRA even though the total mandate
exceeds $100 million.

3According to the RFA, small entities include small businesses, as defined by the SBA; small government
jurisdictions; and small nonprofit organizations. For more details on the definitions of small entities, see

EPA Interim Guidance on Implementing the Small Business Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act and
Related Provisions of the Regulatory Flexibility Act (EPA, 1997f).

6-4


-------
Section 6 — Impact Analyses

that the rule will not have a significant impact on a substantial number of small entities.4 '5
According to EPA Interim Guidance for Implementing the Small Business Regulatory
Enforcement Fairness Act and Related Provisions of the Regulatory Flexibility Act (EPA,
1997f), current Agency policy is to implement the RFA as written; that is, "regulatory
flexibility analyses as specified by the RFA will not be required if the Agency certifies that the
rule will not have significant economic impact on a substantial number of small entities."
However, it remains Agency policy that, even when the Agency makes a certification of "no
significant impact," program offices should assess the impact of every rule on small entities
and minimize any impact to the extent feasible, regardless of the size of the impact or the
number of small entities affected.

Because ISEG has always considered the effects of OAQPS rules on small entities, the
enactment of SBREFA has not precipitated any major changes in ISEG's analysis of the small
entity impacts of a regulatory action. However, as a result of SBREFA, the Agency must take
additional actions when a certification decision is made. For example, if it is determined that
the rule cannot be certified as having "no significant impact," the Agency must convene a
Small Business Advocacy Review Panel.

In accordance with ISEG practice, analysts must conduct a screening analysis to
determine if the rule is likely to have a significant impact on a substantial number of small
entities. Pursuant to SBREFA, the SB A may vary its definition of "small business" by
regulation. These definitions are codified at 13 CF 121.201. ISEG analysts are not required
to use the SB A definitions; however, alternative definitions of "small business" must be
developed in consultation with SB A and are subject to public comment.

In addition, EPA has developed guidelines for what constitutes a significant impact
and the number of firms that constitutes a substantial number of small entities. First, the
analyst must estimate the impact of the regulatory option on businesses, government entities,

4 A certification of "no significant impact" in the proposed rule stage does not preclude an FRFA at the final
rule stage, and an IRFA at the proposed rule stage does not preclude a certification of "no significant
impact" at the final rule stage, because information provided through notice-and-comment rulemaking and
changes to the substance of the rule can change the expected impact of the rule between the proposed and
final stages.

'Although not specifically required by RFA or SBREFA, analysts also may want to analyze the effects of a rule
on minority-owned businesses to support the analysis of environmental justice impacts (see below).

6-5


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

and nonprofit entities of different sizes. The recommended criteria for evaluating the
economic impact of a rule on small entities are presented in Table 6-1.

The preferred criteria for estimating this impact vary across entity types. For small
businesses, the preferred impact measure is annualized costs of the rule as a percentage of
sales ("sales test"). For small government entities, the preferred impact measure is annualized
costs as a percentage of government revenues ("revenue test"). And for small nonprofit
organizations, the preferred impact measure is annualized compliance costs as a percentage of
operating expenditures ("expenditures test"). Other impact measures can be used if
appropriate; however, analysts should consult with ISEG management before doing so.

Table 6-1. Recommended Quantitative Criteria for Evaluating the Economic Impact of
a Rule on Small Entities

Type of Entity and Criteria (preferred criteria in bold italics)

Small Businesses

-	Annualized compliance costs as a percentage of sales ("sales test")

-	Debt-financed capital compliance costs relative to current cash flow ("cash flow
test")

-	Annualized compliance costs as a percentage of before-tax profits ("profit test")

Small Governments

-	Annualized compliance costs as a percentage of annual government revenues
("revenue test")

-	Annualized compliance costs to household (per capita) as a percentage of median
household (per capita) income ("income test")

Small Nonprofit Organizations

-	Annualized compliance costs as a percentage of annual operating expenditures
("expenditures test")

-	Annualized compliance costs as a percentage of total assets ("asset test")	

Source: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. February 5, 1997f. EPA Interim Guidance on Implementing
the Small Business Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act and Related Provisions of the Regulatory
Flexibility Act. Washington, DC: EPA SBREFA Task Force.

6-6


-------
Section 6 — Impact Analyses

These impact measures are then combined with estimates of the absolute number of
small entities that will experience the impact and the percentage of all the small entities subject
to the rule that will experience the impact. Based on estimates of these variables, the rule is
put in one of three categories:

•	Category 1: The rule is presumed to have no significant impact and is certified as
such.6

•	Category 2: No determination of the significance of the impact is assigned to the
rule, and the screening analysis described above, along with a recommendation of
the need for a regulatory flexibility analysis, is presented to the EPA Small
Business Advocacy Chairperson.

•	Category 3: The rule is presumed to be ineligible for certification, so an IRFA or
FRFA should be prepared.

Table 6-2 presents the matrix used to determine the category into which a particular rule will
fall. This table is based on interim Agency guidance. Analysts should keep abreast of changes
in subsequent versions of the RFA guidance document. In addition, analysts should be aware
that the criteria presented in Table 6-2 are only guidance, and analyses based on this guidance
may still be contested by OMB.

The data used to perform the screening analysis should be collected during the
development of the industry profile. See Section 4 for more detail on sources for company
data that can be used in the screening analysis.

If the results of the screening analysis indicate that the rule cannot be certified as
having "no significant impact," then the workgroup must prepare an IRFA. An IFRA must
contain the following information:

•	an explanation of the need for the rule;

•	a statement of the objectives and legal basis for the rule;

•	a description (estimate) of the number of small entities to which the rule will apply;

6If the agency makes a "no significant impact" certification, it must support that certification with a factual
explanation. The results of the screening analysis can be used to support such an explanation.

6-7


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Table 6-2. Summary of Quantitative Information Used to Identify Applicable Categories3

Quantitative Criteria





Number of Small







Entities Experiencing





Number of Small

Economic Impact



Economic Impact Condition

Entities Experiencing

Condition as a

Regulatory

(based on preferred

Economic Impact

Percentage of All

Process

impact criteria)

Condition

Affected Small Entities

Categoryb

Less than 1% for all affected

Any number

Any percent

Category 1

small entities







1% or greater for one or more

Fewer than 100

Any percent

Category 1

small entities0

100 to 999

Less than 20%

Category 1



100 to 999

20% or more

Category 2



1,000 or mored

Any percent

Category 2

3% or greater for one or more

Fewer than 100

Any percent

Category 1

small entities

100 to 999

Less than 20%

Category 2



100 to 999

20% or more

Category 3



1,000 or mored

Any percent

Category 3

a Nothing in this table on applying quantitative measures of economic impacts and enumerating the number
of impacted small entities should be interpreted as indicating that the certification decision is strictly or
solely based on application of the above quantitative steps. Additional information and other factors may be
relevant in deciding whether to prepare a regulatory flexibility analysis or to certify under the RFA.

b In some cases, the extent of the impact (measured in quantitative or qualitative terms) is particularly severe,
even though the number of affected small entities totals fewer than 100 or 20 percent of all affected small
entities. In such cases, the lead office should consider placing the rule in a higher category than would
otherwise be applicable.

c For purposes of applying this portion of the table, the number of small entities that will experience an
impact of 1 percent to 3 percent must be aggregated with the number of small entities that will experience
an impact of 3 percent or greater. The total number of small entities that will experience an impact of
1 percent or greater must be used here to determine whether the number of small entities so impacted is
large enough to warrant preparation of a regulatory flexibility analysis.

d As the number of small entities that will be affected by a rule by more than 1 percent of sales or revenues
approaches 1,000 in number, the substantial number criterion of 20 percent of affected small entities may
become less relevant in determining whether a regulatory flexibility analysis or a certification should be
prepared.

Source: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. February 5, 1997f. EPA Interim Guidance on Implementing
the Small Business Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act and Related Provisions of the Regulatory
Flexibility Act. Washington, DC: EPA SBREFA Task Force.

6-8


-------
Section 6 — Impact Analyses

•	a description of the recordkeeping, reporting, and compliance requirements
contained in the rule, including an estimate of the classes of small entities subject
to the requirement and the level of professional skill needed to prepare required
reports or maintain required records;

•	an identification of other Federal rules that may duplicate, overlap, or conflict with
the rule; and

•	a description of alternatives that accomplish the same stated objectives and may
minimize the impact of the rule on small entities.

The IRFA or a summary of the IRFA must be published in the FR along with the
proposed rule for which it was prepared. If the information required in the IRFA is included
elsewhere in the preamble to the Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (NPRM) or other
rulemaking documents, as is often the case, then the IRFA need not repeat this information
but may simply cross-reference the preamble or other documents.

As a result of recommendations made by the Small Business Advocacy Review Panel
and public comments on the IRFA, rules having significant small business impacts are often
modified between the proposed and final rulemaking stages. These changes may require
modifying the analyses presented in the IRFA or conducting new analyses all together. If new
information or further analysis reveals changes in any of the three screening variables, the
screening process is repeated at the final rule stage. If the screening process again indicates
that the rule cannot be certified as having "no significant impact," then the analyst must
conduct a FRF A. There are four major differences between the requirements for an IFRA and
those for a FRFA:

•	The FRFA does not require an identification of other related Federal rules.

•	The FRFA does not require an analysis of alternatives to the rule.

•	The FRFA must include a summary of the issues raised by public comments and
the agency's response to those issues.

•	The FRFA must contain a description of the steps the agency has taken to
minimize the impact of the rule on small entities consistent with the stated
objectives of the rule.

For further guidance on assessing small entity impacts under the RFA and SBREFA,
analysts are referred to EPA Interim Guidance on Implementing the Small Business

6-9


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act and Related Provisions of the Regulatory Flexibility
Act (EPA, 1997f).

6.3 The Paperwork Reduction Act (PRA)

In many rulemakings, various recordkeeping, reporting, labeling, testing, and other
requirements are included to help EPA verify compliance with the rule after it has been
promulgated. Under the PRA, the Agency is required to estimate the "burden hours"
associated with the recordkeeping and reporting requirements and to weigh this burden
against the "practical utility" of the information collection. This analysis must be presented to
OMB for review in a standardized document known as an ICR.

In general, an ICR is composed of the following elements:

•	a summary of the collection of information;

•	a description of the need for, and proposed use of, the information;

•	a description of the likely respondents, including the number of respondents and
the frequency of response; and

•	an estimate of the total annual reporting and recordkeeping burden that will result
from the information collection.

An outline for a typical ICR is presented in Table 6-3.

The ISEG analyst may play a role in or be primarily responsible for preparing
estimates of burden associated with recordkeeping and reporting requirements presented in
Section 6 of the ICR. The workgroup chair for the rulemaking is usually responsible for
preparing the remainder of the ICR. Cost and burden estimates should reflect any reporting
and recordkeeping costs estimated in the cost section of the EIA. It is important to note,
however, that the reporting and recordkeeping costs included in the ICR are estimated over a
period of 3 years. In contrast, the reporting and recordkeeping costs estimated in the cost
section of the EIA span the entire period of analysis considered in the EIA. These estimates
should include the total time and resources needed to

•	review instructions;

6-10


-------
Section 6 — Impact Analyses

Table 6-3. Contents of the Supporting Statement for an Information Collection
Request

1.	Identification of the Information Collection

1(a) Title of Information Collection, Title of Corresponding Rule, EPA ICR Number, and
Existing OMB Approval Number (if ICR is a renewal of or amendment to an existing
information collection)

1(b) Short Characterization (Abstract)

2.	Need for the Information Collection
2(a) Need/Authority for the Collection
2(b) Use/Users of the Data

3.	The Respondents and the Information Requested
3(a) Respondent SIC Codes

3(b) Information Requested

4.	The Information Collected—Agency Activities, Collection, Methodology, and Information
Management

4(a)	Agency Activities

4(b)	Collection Methodology and Management

4(c)	Small Entity Flexibility

4(d)	Collection Schedule

5.	Nonduplication, Consultations, and Other Collection Criteria
5(a)	Nonduplication of Existing Information Collections
5(b)	Consultations with Stakeholders

5(c) Effects of Less Frequent Collection
5(d) Compliance with OMB Guidelines
5(e) Confidentiality and Sensitive Questions

6.	Estimating Burden and Cost of the Collection
6(a) Estimating Respondent Burden and Costs
6(b) Estimating Agency Burden and Cost

6(c) Bottom Line Burden and Cost-Master Table
6(d) Change in Burden (if renewal of an existing ICR)

	6(e) Burden Statement	

6-11


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

•	develop systems for the purpose of collecting, validating, and verifying
information; processing and maintaining information; and disclosing or providing
information;

•	adjust current practice to comply with the recordkeeping and reporting
requirements;

•	train personnel to respond to an information collection;

•	search data sources;

•	complete and review the information collection; and

•	transmit or disclose the information.

Analysts should consult the Office of Policy (OP) ICR Handbook (EPA, 1998e) when
preparing recordkeeping and reporting cost estimates to be included in an ICR.

As part of the statement of need for the proposed action, the ICR should also describe
the practical utility of the information to be collected, maintained, or disclosed. 5 CFR 1320
defines practical utility as "the actual...usefulness of the information to or for an agency,
taking into account its accuracy, validity, adequacy, and reliability, and the agency's ability to
process the information it collects...in a timely fashion." Practical utility is typically
established by qualitatively describing the use of the information. The discussion of practical
utility is usually left to the workgroup.

6.4 Distributional Impacts

The benefits and costs of a rule are often distributed unevenly across different sectors
of the economy or among different categories of individuals. The statutory requirements for
impact analysis discussed in the preceding sections generally address the distribution of costs
across sectors of the economy, including governments and the private sector. In addition,
UMRA requires that analysts identify the distribution of costs across different geographic
regions. The distribution of benefits and costs among different categories of individuals often
evokes concerns about equity and fairness; however, because most EAs attempt to measure
benefits and costs in the aggregate, the distribution of those benefits and costs can easily be
overlooked. Also, EO 12866 (Regulatory Planning and Review) includes the reduction of
discrimination or bias among the possible benefits of a regulation to be considered. Therefore,
this section identifies the various ways in which the distributional effects can be examined to
more fully inform decisionmakers of the consequences of a regulatory action.

6-12


-------
Section 6 — Impact Analyses

The impacts of a regulation may be distributed unevenly across a number of personal
or demographic characteristics.7 These characteristics include income, gender, race, and age.
Also, decisionmakers may be interested in the impact of a regulation on certain sensitive
subpopulations. Although the term "sensitive subpopulations" is not clearly defined, it is often
used in reference to individuals whose existing health status may make them especially
vulnerable to environmental hazards. While impact analyses can be conducted to determine
the distribution of effects across any or all of these categories, two EOs (12898 and 13045)
specifically require Federal agencies to consider the three primary characteristics (income,
race, and age) when proposing or promulgating a regulation:

•	EO 12898—Federal Actions to Address Environmental Justice in Minority
Populations and Low-Income Population—requires each agency to address and
identify "...disproportionately high and adverse human health or environmental
effects of its programs, policies, and activities on minority and low-income
populations..." (Section 1.1). An analysis of the distribution of benefits and costs
of a regulation across individuals of different races and levels of income serves to
inform decisionmakers of the environmental justice consequences of OAQPS
regulations.8

•	EO 13045—Protection of Children from Environmental Health Risks and Safety
Risks—requires that Federal agencies examine the impacts of each regulatory
action on children for any economically significant regulation (as defined by

EO 12866) that the agency has reason to believe may disproportionately affect
children. This EO implicitly requires an analysis of the distribution of impacts
across age cohorts within the population for any OAQPS regulation designed to
protect human health.9

determining the distribution of impacts involves more than estimating impacts on identified subpopulations.
In particular, ascertaining if disparate impacts exist involves determining if observed differences are
statistically significant. In many cases, however, the data are insufficient to make such a determination.

8Although the Agency has not developed guidance for specifically addressing environmental justice concerns
in its rulemakings, two documents provide overviews of environmental justice and may be of interest to
analysts: Interim Final Guidance for Incorporating Environmental Justice Concerns in EPA's NEPA
Compliance Analysis (EPA, 1997h) and Evaluating the Equity of Environmental Policy Options Based on
the Distribution of Economic Effects: Preliminary Draft (EPA, 1997g).

'Although the Agency has not developed guidance for addressing impacts on children, analysts are again
referred to Evaluating the Equity of Environmental Policy Options Based on the Distribution of Economic
Effects: Preliminary Draft (EPA, 1997g) for an overview of equity considerations based on age.

6-13


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

As mentioned above, unevenly distributed economic impacts often result in concerns
about equity and fairness. Although classical economics and benefit-cost analysis avoid the
direct evaluation of fairness, an analysis of the distribution of impacts across various segments
of society provides decisionmakers with a framework in which to judge the equity of a
regulatory action. In an effort to incorporate notions of equity and fairness in EPA
decisionmaking, OP has drafted Evaluating the Equity of Environmental Policy Options
Based on the Distribution of Economic Effects: Preliminary Draft (EPA, 1997g). This
document provides guidance on how to incorporate distributional impacts analysis into an EA.
In particular, the following recommendations are made:

•	Do not address very low impact regulations, options, and effects. For regulations
with small distributional impacts, the additional information provided by an impact
analysis may not warrant the resources required to conduct the analysis.

•	Identify and define the personal and demographic characteristics (e.g., race, age)
of concern. In this step, the analyst should list all expected distributional effects
and prioritize them.

•	Determine the limits of the analysis by identifying the markets in which
distributional effects are expected to occur.

•	Determine whether distributional impacts exist within the scope of the analysis,
noting that, in some cases, distributional effects may not occur in the markets
directly affected by the regulation.

•	Measure distributional impacts using a range of assumptions to characterize the
possible distributions of expected impacts.

•	Examine distributional impacts over the expected course of market adjustments
because some impacts may be a direct result of markets adjusting to regulatory
requirements and may change over time.

6.5 Structural Impacts

In addition to distributional impacts, a regulation may result in fundamental changes in
more aggregate macroeconomic variables such as trade, innovation, inflation, and
employment. EO 12866 explicitly calls for an analysis of productivity, employment, and
competitiveness impacts as part of the assessment of the potential costs of a regulatory action.
Likewise, the written statement prepared pursuant to UMRA must include an assessment of
the impact of a regulation "on the national economy, such as the effect on productivity,

6-14


-------
Section 6 — Impact Analyses

economic growth, full employment, creation of productive jobs, and international
competitiveness of United States goods and services." The assessment must be performed
"to the extent that the agency in its sole discretion determines that accurate estimates are
reasonably feasible and that such effect is relevant and material" (UMRA, Section 202(a)). A
memorandum to the heads of executive departments and agencies from OMB (Katzen, 1995)
provides further guidance for analyzing structural impacts under UMRA.10

Unlike distributional impacts, structural impacts require more than simply
disaggregating benefits and costs to determine their effect on different segments of society.
Instead, an analysis of structural impacts usually requires that the analyst trace the effects of a
regulation beyond the market or economic sector in which they directly occur to determine
the impact on the economy as a whole.

Analyses of structural impacts often require either multiple partial equilibrium analyses
or some form of general equilibrium analysis. Because computing benefits and costs in
multiple markets can significantly raise the cost of analysis, the analyst should first informally
assess whether the rule is likely to have macroeconomic impacts. This will generally depend
on the size of the affected industry and whether it engages in international trade. If the
informal assessment reveals that such impacts are likely, the analyst should consult ISEG
management about how best to apply time and resources to such an analysis.

10This memo does, however, contain an error of which ISEG analysts should be aware. The memo notes that
macroeconomic impacts are measurable only if the impact of the rule exceeds 0.25 to 0.5 percent of gross
domestic product and indicates that this range is equal to $1.5 billion to $3 billion. GDP in 1997 totaled
approximately $8.1 trillion. Therefore, 0.25 percent to 0.5 percent of GDP would total approximately
$20 billion to $40 billion. It is not clear whether the percentages or the dollar amounts are in error.
Therefore, ISEG analysts should use caution when using the guidance provided in this memo.

6-15


-------
Section 7 — Framework for Quantitative Benefits Analysis

SECTION 7

FRAMEWORK FOR QUANTITATIVE BENEFITS ANALYSIS

As described in Section 2 of this document, OAQPS has the authority to undertake
the following regulatory actions:

•	set national ambient air quality standards (NAAQS) for six "criteria" pollutants;

•	establish national emissions standards for 189 listed hazardous air pollutants
(NESHAP);

•	establish new source performance standards (NSPS), imposing technology-based
requirements on new or modified major sources of pollutants;

•	establish emissions standards for mobile sources;

•	impose requirements to address specific air pollution problems, such as acid rain
and depletion of stratospheric ozone;

•	establish nonattainment areas for regions that have failed to meet the NAAQS
standards for one or more of the criteria pollutants; and

•	require each State to submit a plan for the implementing and enforcing national
standards, thus referred to as State Implementation Plans (SIP). Also required
within each SIP are measures to ensure against significant deterioration of air
quality in areas that meet NAAQS standards.

In the case of NAAQS, OAQPS sets limits on ambient concentrations of six "criteria"
pollutants, allowing the States to determine how best to achieve these standards. For
NESHAPs, NSPS, and emissions standards for mobile sources, OAQPS places limits on the
quantity of releases of pollutants into the atmosphere. Although the specific focus of these
rulemakings may differ, the ultimate objective is the same. As a result, the benefits of all
OAQPS regulations can be described as a function of reductions in human health and
environmental impacts caused by exposure of humans and the environment to ambient
concentrations of air pollutants. The purpose of this section is to describe a framework for
estimating these benefits.

7-1


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

7.1 Economic Benefits: An Overview

The benefits of an environmental regulation generally consist of the effects that an
improvement in environmental quality has on human welfare. Individuals derive satisfaction
(abstractly known as utility) from the services provided by the natural environment. To the
extent that improvements in the quality of the natural environment improve the service flows
provided to humans, individuals experience a utility gain. Conversely, any damage to the
physical environment that decreases the quantity or quality of these service flows results in a
utility loss. In this context, the atmosphere can be viewed as a natural asset, the services of
which include (but are not limited to) such things as life support for humans and other living
things, as well as visual amenities. Changes in air quality that result from pollution hinder
the atmosphere's ability to provide such service flows to humans.

To understand the effect that an environmental regulation has on the service flows
provided by the natural environment, one must consider three functional relationships
(Freeman, 1993). The first relationship describes the effect of human activities on
environmental quality. This relationship estimates ambient concentrations of pollutants in
environmental media as a function of air emissions. Fate and transport models are used to
characterize this relationship. The second functional relationship is that between
environmental quality and the service flows provided by the natural environment. This
relationship characterizes such service flows as a function of ambient pollution
concentrations, usually in the form of concentration-response or dose-response function. The
third, and final, relationship translates environmental service flows into human welfare. The
use of these functional relationships in estimating the benefits of a regulation is presented in
Figure 7-1.

Recall from the discussion above that the benefits of OAQPS regulations result from
changes in emissions to the atmosphere. Therefore, the first functional relationship presented
in Figure 7-1 relates these changes in emissions to changes in ambient concentrations of
pollutants in environmental media through fate and transport models. The boxes at the top of
Figure 7-1 represent emissions under two different states of the world—the baseline and the
control. The baseline corresponds to the state of the world in the absence of the regulation.
In contrast, the control corresponds to the level of emissions in a world with the regulation.
The difference between these emissions levels is the primary result of the regulation.

7-2


-------
Section 7 — Framework for Quantitative Benefits Analysis

CS

fl

§•2

Baseline Pollutant
Emissions





o Q-

*-s

fi c

S o
¦O -2

fl «

S3

© .ST

pC

-j 5«

a	S
s .2

"2 «

.2	ca

-S5

With-Control Pollutant
Emissions





>

r

Changes in Environmental
Service Flows

>

r

Figure 7-1. Functional Relationships in Benefits Analysis

7-3


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Once the change in ambient concentrations has been estimated by applying fate and
transport models to the change in emissions, the analyst must use concentration-response
relationships or dose-response relationships to determine reductions in the damages resulting
from the changes in ambient concentrations.1 Economic valuation methods can then be used
to estimate the value individuals place on these improved environmental service flows.

7.2 Steps in Conducting Benefits Analysis

As a practical matter, there are three primary steps to estimating the benefits of an
environmental regulation. First, the analyst must identify the reductions in human health and
environmental damages expected to result from the regulation. Next, these identified benefits
must be quantified. And finally, quantified benefits should be expressed in monetary terms
to the extent possible. In the sections that follow, these steps are described relative to the
functional relationships presented above.

7.2.1 Identifying Benefits

Identifying the benefits of a regulation is analogous to identifying the reductions in
damages to environmental service flows attributable to the rule. The damages that can be
avoided by reducing pollutant emissions fall into three broad categories (adapted from
Freeman, 1993):

1. Direct damages to humans, including health damages and aesthetic damages;

-	Health damages result from human exposure to pollutants. These damages
include increases in the risk of death (mortality risk) or increases in the risk of
experiencing an adverse health effect (morbidity risk). Adverse health effects
can be divided into acute effects such as headaches or eye irritation which
generally last only a few days, and chronic effects such as emphysema or
asthma which are generally associated with long-term illness.

-	Aesthetic damages result from contamination of the physical environment and
include increased problems of odor, noise, and poor visibility.

'Although characterizing and estimating the first two functional relationships are tasks for risk assessors, the
steps required to conduct these analyses are described in this section so that ISEG analysts have a clear
understanding of the benefits to be monetized in an economic analysis.

7-4


-------
Section 7 — Framework for Quantitative Benefits Analysis

2.	Indirect damages to humans through ecosystems, including productivity damages,
recreation damages, and intrinsic or nonuse damages;

-	Productivity damages, including reduced productivity of farmland, forests,
and commercial fisheries, result from pollution damages to physical
environments which support these commercial activities.

-	Recreation damages result from the reduced quality of environmental
resources such as lakes and rivers used for recreational activities.

-	Intrinsic or nonuse damages include losses in the value people associate with
preserving, protecting, and improving the quality of ecological resources that
is not motivated by their own use of those resources.

3.	Indirect damages to humans through nonliving systems, including damages to
materials and structures (e.g., buildings and equipment) that are caused by
pollution and can reduce the productivity of these assets.

The process of identifying the benefits of a regulation is equivalent to qualitatively
describing the first and second functional relationships presented in Figure 7-1. That is,
identifying benefits essentially involves describing the relationship between changes in
pollutant emissions and ambient concentrations in environmental media and then describing
the relationship between those ambient pollution concentrations and the services provided by
the physical environment. Figure 7-2 outlines the linkages between NOx emissions and
environmental damages.

As is evident from the amount of activity in the figure between pollution emissions
and ambient concentrations, the fate and transport of pollutant emissions through the
atmosphere usually involve a number of interactions between the emissions of interest and
other atmospheric constituents. In particular, NOx has both direct effects on human health
and the environment and indirect (precursor) effects resulting from its interaction with other
chemicals in the atmosphere. Therefore, care should be taken when describing the fate and
transport of pollutant emissions through the environment. Likewise, the relationship between
ambient pollutant concentrations and environmental damages can also be complex.

7-5


-------
OA QPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Figure 7-2. Functional Relationships Between NOx Emissions and Environmental
Service Flows

Based on a figure in DOE (1993).

7-6


-------
Section 7 — Framework for Quantitative Benefits Analysis

7.2.2 Quantifying Benefits

Just as identifying the benefits of a regulation requires qualitatively describing the
first and second functional relationships presented in Figure 7-1, quantifying benefits requires
calculating the effects that changes in emissions have on environmental service flows. This
involves quantifying changes in emissions, using fate and transport models to estimate the
corresponding changes in ambient concentrations of pollutants in environmental media, and
then estimating dose-response or concentration-response relationships2 to translate these
changes in ambient concentrations into quantitative changes in environmental damages.

7.2.2.1 Quantifying Health Benefits

In general, quantifying health benefits involves six steps. These steps include
determining the following:

1.	the dose-response relationship for each health effect,

2.	total exposure in the absence of the regulation,

3.	the number of baseline cases for each quantifiable health effect,

4.	total exposure with the regulation (for each regulatory alternative),

5.	the number of cases for each quantifiable health effect with the regulation (for
each regulatory alternative), and

6.	the number of cases avoided as a result of each alternative.

Each of these steps is described below.

Step 1: Determining the Dose-Response Relationship for Each Health Effect

A dose-response relationship is an estimate of risk per unit of exposure to a pollutant.
For cancer assessments, dose-response has typically been modeled as a linear no-threshold
relationship; that is, every unit of exposure contributes equally to aggregate risk. For

2 A dose-response estimate is a value that quantifies the increased risk of incidence of some health effect

associated with a one-unit increase in exposure to a pollutant. A concentration-response estimate is a value
that quantifies the increase in some environmental damage associated with a one-unit increase in the
ambient concentration of a pollutant.

7-7


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

example, 100 units of human exposure result in a given amount of risk, regardless of whether
there is a one-time exposure of 100 units to one person, ten exposures of one unit each to ten
different people, or one-time exposures of one unit each to 100 different people. However,
the Agency has been moving toward the use of nonlinear health effects models. These models
may become more prevalent in future analyses. For noncancer health effects, dose-response
relationships may include a threshold and/or may be nonlinear with respect to the level of
exposure.

Step 2: Determining Baseline Exposure

Human exposure to a pollutant is a function of ambient concentrations of that
pollutant in environmental media. Determining baseline exposure requires estimating two
parameters. First, analysts must identify the exposed populations (e.g., occupational groups,
consumers of particular products, the general population living in a particular area) and the
number of exposed individuals in each group. Then one needs to determine the level,
duration, route, and frequency of exposure (e.g., 100 ppm time-weighted average exposure
for an 8-hour day, 50 days per year).

At this point in the discussion, it is important to note that individuals may take action
to reduce their exposure to harmful substances. For example, individuals may purchase
bottled water to avoid exposure to contaminants found in tap water. Such averting behaviors
affect the size of the exposed population. Therefore, any exposure assessment should take
into account individual actions designed to reduce exposure. However, inclusion of such
behavior is usually, at best, only implicit in the exposure assessment. As a result, in the
remainder of this section, the discussion of averting behavior in an economic analysis is limited
to the use of averting expenditures as a proxy for individual WTP to avoid the health effects
expected to result from human exposure to environmental contaminants (see Section 7.2.3.1).

Step 3: Determining the Number of Baseline Cases for Each Quantifiable Health Effect

The number of baseline cases for each quantifiable health effect is the product of the
baseline number of people exposed, the amount (level, duration, and frequency) of baseline
exposure, and the dose-response relationship; that is, the baseline number of cases for each
exposed population equals:

Number exposed x Baseline exposure x Dose-response relationship.

7-8


-------
Section 7 — Framework for Quantitative Benefits Analysis

Step 4: Determining Exposure after the Regulation (for Each Regulatory Option)

Each regulatory option may result in a reduction in the exposure level, a reduction in
the exposed population, or some combination of the two. Therefore, there are two
dimensions to characterizing post-regulatory exposure. First, it is necessary to estimate the
impact of the option on exposure levels. For example, a regulatory option may reduce (but
not eliminate) the exposure to the pollutant from a particular exposure pathway. Second, it is
necessary to estimate the expected post-regulatory level of exposure for that exposure
pathway.

Step 5: Determining the Number of Cases for Each Quantifiable Effect with the Regulation
(for Each Regulatory Option)

In this step, Step 3 is repeated, using the post-regulatory estimates of exposure
(number of people exposed; frequency, duration, and level of exposure) derived in Step 4.
Multiplying the new exposure estimates by the dose-response estimate yields an estimate of
the post-regulatory number of cases.

Step 6: Determining the Number of Cases Avoided as a Result of Each Regulatory Option

To determine the number of statistical cases avoided as a result of a regulatory option,
the number of post-regulatory cases (from Step 5) is subtracted from the baseline number of
cases (from Step 3). The difference is the quantified benefits of the regulation as follows:

Estimating the concentration-response relationship provides an alternative to the six-
step process outlined above. Although estimating individual risk per unit of exposure and
then multiplying this estimate by total exposure is the more accurate method of quantifying
health effects, the data required for such an analysis are often not available. In those cases, it
may be possible to estimate the extent of health effects as a function of ambient concentrations
of pollutants in the atmosphere. This process involves the determining the following:

Quantified
Health
Effects

Baseline Cases
Resulting from
Exposure to
Pollutant

Post-Regulatory
Cases Resulting
from Exposure to
Pollutant

7-9


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

1.	the concentration-response ratio for each health effect,

2.	ambient pollutant concentrations in the absence of the regulation,

3.	ambient pollutant concentrations with the regulation (for each regulatory
alternative),

4.	the number of cases for each health effect with the regulation (for each regulatory
alternative), and

5.	the number of cases avoided as a result of each alternative.

This process differs from the six-step process described above only in that the
estimation of a dose-response relationship and exposure for each health effect for each
regulatory alternative are combined into one step—the estimation of a concentration-response
relationship. A concentration-response relationship is an estimate of the number of health
effects associated with a given ambient pollutant concentration (e.g., number of asthma
attacks associated with a particular concentration of ground-level ozone). If the ambient
concentration of the pollutant is known both with and without the regulation, then a
concentration-response relationship can be used to estimate changes in the number of health
effects resulting from the regulation. Examples of concentration-response relationships for
health effects developed in the literature include Schwartz (1993), Ostro and Rothchild
(1989), and Pope (1989).

7.2.2.2 Quantifying Ecological Benefits

Quantifying ecological benefits is similar to quantifying health benefits using
concentration-response relationships. In particular, when the effect of a regulation on the
ambient concentrations of a pollutant can be estimated, and the relationship between ambient
pollution concentrations and environmental service flows is known, then the ecological
benefits of a regulation can be quantified. For example, the National Crop Loss Assessment
Network (NCLAN) developed concentration-response relationships linking ground-level
ozone to leaf damage and reduced seed size in an effort to determine the effect of ozone on
crop yields.3 Other sources of concentration-response relationships for ecological damages
include Martin and Banzhaf (1994); Heagle, Spencer, and Letchworth (1979); Kopp,
Vaughan, and Hazilla (1984); Brewer and Ashcroft (1982); Oshima et al. (1976); Leung,

3For information about the design and results of the specific NCLAN experiments, refer to Heck et al. (1982).
7-10


-------
Section 7 — Framework for Quantitative Benefits Analysis

Reed, and Geng (1982); Foster et al. (1983); Rowe and Chestnut (1985); Clark, Henninger,
and Brennan (1983); and Keller (1985).

7.2.2.3 Quantifying Benefits through Nonliving Systems

Degradation of many materials, including metals, masonry, and paints, is accelerated
by exposure to pollutants. For example, corrosion rates for galvanized steel and zinc as well
as erosion rates of carbonate stone have been studied and strongly linked to acidic deposition.
Building stone, which includes limestone and marble, is also affected by pollutant emissions.
Painted surfaces incur the largest economic losses from pollutant exposures (Bernabo et al.,
1988). Although the physical links between pollutant emissions and materials damages are
well established, the precise quantitative relationship between degradation rates and exposures
are not. The effectiveness of preventive maintenance has further complicated the assessment
of pollution damages. Therefore, quantifying the effects of pollutant emissions on materials
and structures may be quite difficult. Nonetheless, because reductions in materials damages
could constitute a significant economic benefit of an air quality regulation, it is important to
describe these effects to the greatest extent possible, even if only qualitatively.

7.2.3 Monetizing Benefits

Monetizing the benefits of a regulation involves estimating society's willingness to pay
(WTP) for quantified changes in environmental service flows. In economics, WTP refers to
the maximum amount an individual is willing to pay to acquire a benefit. It is measured as the
reduction in income required to return an individual to the level of utility he or she enjoyed
prior to receiving the benefit. An alternative measure of economic value is an individual's
willingness to accept (WTA) compensation to forego a benefit. Conceptually, WTA is
measured as the minimum compensation to required for an individual to achieve the same
level of utility he or she would have attained if the benefit had been realized. From a
theoretical perspective, the appropriate measure (WTP or WTA) depends on the implicit
property rights in the valuation context, and the two measures should be close in value. WTP
estimates have been generally preferred in the empirical economics literature. The remainder
of this section is devoted to describing the methods used to estimate WTP for environmental
improvements.

7-11


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

7.2.3.1 Monetizing Health Benefits

Nonfatal Illness and Injury (Morbidity). Economists use a number of approaches to
monetize a change in the number of cases of a particular morbidity effect. The four primary
approaches are cost-of-illness (COI) methods, expressed preference methods, averting action
methods, and hedonic wage and property value methods. Of these, COI methods are most
often employed in economic analyses of human health benefits. Other methods include risk-
risk tradeoffs, health state indexes, and damage award approaches. The four primary
approaches are examined below.4

Cost-of-Illness Approach. Because of the difficulties associated with generating or
using estimates of WTP for reductions in the risk of nonfatal illness or injury, analysts often
prefer valuation methods based on the avoided costs of illness or injury. The COI approach to
morbidity valuation measures the direct and indirect costs resulting from a health effect.

Direct costs include such things as the value of goods and services used to diagnose and treat
individuals suffering from the health effect. Indirect costs consist primarily of foregone
productivity measured by lost wages. Total COI is the sum of direct and indirect costs.
Because the COI approach does not account for the full range of costs associated with an
illness or injury (e.g., pain and suffering are not included), the results of these analyses should
at best be viewed as lower-bound estimates of society's WTP for reductions in such risks.

As mentioned above, the theoretically appropriate measure of economic benefits is
society's WTP to reduce the risk of a health effect (i.e., society's WTP to avoid the risk prior
to the actual occurrence of a health effect). It is important to note that the COI approach
measures costs after a health effect has occurred rather than an individual's WTP to avoid the
health effect in the first place. In addition, the COI approach measures the costs to the
individual (out-of-pocket costs and lost wages), the costs to the individual's employer (in the
case of paid sick leave), and the costs to third-party payers (payment of insured medical
expenses or charity care), but not changes in individual well-being caused by the illness.

There are two primary approaches to measuring COI: the prevalence approach and
the incidence approach. The prevalence approach measures total costs of a particular illness

4For a thorough discussion of the Ml set of methods used to value nonfatal health effects, readers are referred
to IEc (1997).

7-12


-------
Section 7 — Framework for Quantitative Benefits Analysis

or injury in the population for a given year. In contrast, the incidence approach measures the
cost of an individual case of illness from onset through recovery or death. For assessing the
benefits of OAQPS regulations, the incidence approach to measuring the cost of an illness or
injury is most appropriate because the health benefits of OAQPS regulations are typically
expressed in terms of the number of cases of a particular health effect avoided as a result of
the regulatory action. Use of the prevalence approach would be appropriate if the effect of a
regulation eliminated a particular health effect.

Expressed Preference Methods. Expressed preference methods, including contingent
valuation (CV) and conjoint analysis, can be used to elicit an individual's WTP to avoid a
given health effect. CV techniques are the primary expressed preference method used to
estimate health effects. CV uses surveys to directly elicit an individual's WTP to reduce the
risk of a given health effect. In particular, a CV survey asks each respondent about his or her
personal characteristics, attitudes concerning the commodity being valued (reductions in the
risk of an adverse health effect in this case), and WTP to acquire the commodity. From the
survey responses, analysts can estimate WTP to reduce the risk of an adverse health effect as
a function of personal characteristics and attitudes.

Although they are the most broadly applicable valuation methods, CV techniques
remain controversial because of their hypothetical nature. In particular, there are two primary
criticisms of CV. First, because an individual will not actually have to pay the amount he or
she indicates in response to the survey, the individual may have little incentive to respond
truthfully. Second, critics contend that survey respondents often are unable to comprehend
the commodity they are being asked to value; particularly when the commodity is a very small
change in the risk of experiencing a health effect. Proponents of CV assert that many of the
problems raised by critics can be effectively controlled through good survey design. Although
OAQPS generally does not conduct original CV studies due to time and other resource
constraints, analysts should be mindful of these criticisms when using existing CV estimates to
monetize benefits.5

Rather than directly asking an individual his or her WTP, conjoint methods ask
individuals to choose among different sets of alternatives. Each alternative is broken down

'Analysts planning to use WTP estimates developed using the CV method are referred to the fall 1994 issue of
the Journal of Economic Perspectives for a more thorough discussion of the debate over CV. A detailed
discussion of benefits transfer issues is presented in Section 7.3.

7-13


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

and described according to a common set of attributes, usually including the health effect of
interest and some monetary measure. The levels of these attributes are varied across
alternatives. By analyzing an individual's choices across a number of pairs of alternatives,
analysts can derive estimates of the trade-offs the individual is willing to make among the
different attributes (including cost), thereby estimating the individual's WTP to acquire a
change in an attribute such as reduced risk of a specific health effect. Although conjoint
analyses show promise in valuing health effects, these techniques are not commonly used for
such a purpose.

Averting Action Methods. In the face of a potential risk, individuals will often take
defensive or averting action. For example, in the case of groundwater contamination, averting
action might include purchases of water filters, bottled water, and other alternative water
supplies. In the case of air pollution, averting actions may include such things as avoiding
going out of doors. These types of observable behavior can provide analysts with information
about an individual's WTP to avoid specific health risks; however, more generally they
provide information about the costs of these behaviors, their relation to the source of such
risk, and the magnitude of cost savings that would result from controlling the source.

As noted above, examining averting behavior provides the analyst with information
regarding individuals' WTP to avoid exposure to a source of risk. Averting actions taken in
response to risk may also enter the regulatory analysis in the risk assessment to the extent that
these actions reduce the overall exposure of the population to harmful pollutants. If the
exposure assessment of a regulatory analysis takes into account changes in averting behavior
between the baseline and control scenarios, then the cost savings attributable to the reduced
need for averting action can be considered one component of the benefits of the rule. When
examining expected reductions in averting behavior, the analyst must be careful not to double
count. In particular, analysts must estimate the benefits to those who, because of the rule,
change their averting behavior separately from those who experience a reduction in exposure
(and subsequent risk) without changing their own averting behavior. To the former, averting
expenditures measure potential cost savings resulting from the rule. To the latter, averting
expenditures provide an estimate of WTP to avoid exposure.

Averting action methods are often preferred to expressed preference methods because
they are based on actual behavior; however, measuring the benefits and costs of averting
actions is often difficult. First, to determine an individual's WTP to avoid a specific health

7-14


-------
Section 7 — Framework for Quantitative Benefits Analysis

effect by examining his or her averting behavior, it may be necessary to determine the benefit
the individual expects to receive as a result of his or her averting actions. Second, averting
actions are typically taken to avoid a health outcome by reducing the individual's exposure to
a harmful event. Therefore, WTP measures estimated based on averting actions are usually
employed as estimates of WTP to avoid exposure and not as measures of WTP to avoid a
specific health effect.6 Therefore, using averting action methods to value specific health
outcomes of an OAQPS rulemaking may be difficult.

Hedonic Methods. Two common applications of hedonic methods are used to value
changes in health risks: hedonic wage models and hedonic property value models. Hedonic
wage models are based on the premise that, all else equal, an individual working in a risky
occupation will require higher compensation for his or her labor than will the same individual
working in a less risky occupation. By examining wage differentials among individuals
working in various occupations, analysts can estimate a worker's WTA for exposure to higher
levels of risk on the job.

Hedonic property value models are based on the theory that the price of a residential
property is equal to the discounted present value of the lifetime residential value of the home.
The price of the home can then be estimated as a function of its structural characteristics and
the characteristics of the surrounding community. By estimating housing prices over a range
of properties, each with varying structural and community characteristics (including air
quality), analysts can infer a household's WTP for each of these characteristics. For a good
example of a hedonic study designed to estimate the value of avoiding environmental health
risks, see Mendelsohn et al. (1992).

Fatality. The benefits of OAQPS regulations can also include reductions in the risk of
premature death. The economics literature discussing the value of changes in fatality risks is
rather extensive and provides a relatively strong basis for monetizing benefits when the
number of deaths avoided as a result of a regulatory action can be calculated.

Value of a Statistical Life (VSL). Monetary estimates of changes in fatality risk are
often expressed in terms of the VSL. The term "value of a statistical life" is easily
misinterpreted and should be carefully described when used in benefits analysis. In particular,

6One exception is Dickie and Gerking (1991) who use individuals' expenditures on air conditioning and
electric (rather than gas) stoves to model WTP to avoid acute health effects of air pollution.

7-15


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

VSL refers to the WTP for reductions in the risk of premature death aggregated over the
population experiencing the risk reduction; that is, VSL refers to the sum of many small
reductions in fatality risks.7 For example, if the annual risk of death is reduced by 1 in
1,000,000 for each of 2,000,000 people, then two statistical lives are saved each year as a
result of the risk reduction measures. If each individual is willing to pay $5 for the risk
reduction of 1 in 1,000,000, then the value of each statistical life saved is $5 million.

The basic assumption underlying the VSL approach is that equal increments in fatality
risks are valued equally. For example, a reduction in the risk of death of 1 in 1,000,000 is
valued the same whether or not the original fatality risk was 1 in 100,000 or 1 in 1,000,000.
This assumption is generally defensible if the level of risk prior to the change is small (usually
1 in 100,000 or less) as is usually the case for fatality risks resulting from environmental
hazards. Because economic theory maintains that the marginal utility of risk reduction is an
increasing function of the level of baseline risk, this assumption may not be valid for risks
greater than 1 in 100,000.8 For similar reasons, the VSL approach is only appropriate for
marginal changes in the risk of death and should not be used to value more significant
changes. Because changes in individual fatality risks resulting from environmental regulation
are typically very small, the VSL approach is usually acceptable for OAQPS benefits analyses.

The literature indicates that empirical estimates of WTP for risk reduction are sensitive
to whether the risk is borne voluntarily. In general, it is believed that risk-averse individuals
have a greater WTP for marginal risk reductions than those who choose risks voluntarily.
Because most VSL studies are based on wage compensation data, the results are applicable to
changes in voluntary risks, and the population over which these values are estimated is often
not representative of the population affected by a regulation; however, because, as noted
above, fatality risks from both involuntary environmental hazards and occupational fatality
risks tend to be quite small, using VSL estimates developed using wage compensation data is
reasonable.

In the past, most EPA analyses have used point estimates of VSL derived from the
economics literature. There are two alternatives to this approach. First, analysts could apply

7It is important to note that VSL does not attempt to value the life of an identified individual.

8See Chapter 10 of Freeman (1993) for a more detailed discussion of the diminishing marginal utility of risk
reduction.

7-16


-------
Section 7 — Framework for Quantitative Benefits Analysis

a range of VSL values found in the existing literature to develop upper- and lower-bound
estimates of the total value of lives saved as a result of a regulation. This approach, however,
often gives equal weight to very high and very low estimates that may be found infrequently in
the literature. Alternatively, analysts could use distributions of VSL values rather than point
estimates or ranges. Distributions give quantitative weights to the likely accuracy of the
different VSL estimates based on the frequency with which they are found in the existing
literature.

In assessing the benefits of the CAA, analysts conducted a meta-analysis of VSL
estimates found in the literature and fit the results to a Weibull distribution to characterize the
range of possible benefit values (EPA, 1996a). This approach revealed that the majority of
VSL estimates found in the literature tend to cluster in the range of $3 million to $7 million,
with a central estimate of approximately $5 million. A review of methods used by EPA in
valuing changes in mortality risks conducted for OP by Chestnut, Mills, and Alberini (1997)
notes that there is an insufficient empirical basis to justify the disparity in VSL estimates
chosen across programs within the Agency. Although this report does not recommend
specific VSL estimates to be used in EPA economic analyses, it does suggest that the central
tendency of $5 million revealed in the CAA benefits analysis may provide the best starting
point.

Value of a Statistical Life Year (VSLY). An alternative method of expressing
reductions in mortality risk is the VSLY. For example, if a regulation is estimated to save one
statistical life among a population of working adults whose average life expectancy is
40 years, then the regulation would result in 40 life-years extended. In general, there are two
methods for valuing the number of life-years extended:

•	applying results from studies in which the WTP for a risk reduction is estimated as
a function of age; and

•	annualizing VSL estimates using an appropriate discount rate and average life
expectancy.

Both of these approaches have some fundamental shortcomings. In particular, when deriving
values of risk reduction as a function of age, the type of risk and the size of the marginal
change in risk used to estimate the value of a risk reduction must closely match the risk
reductions resulting from the regulation. Annualizing VSL estimates does not provide an
independent estimate of VSLY but simply rescales the VSL estimate. Current research does

7-17


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

not suggest a definitive method for estimating VSLY that is sensitive to such variables as
current age, latency period, life-years remaining, and the social value of different risk
reductions.

7.2.3.2 Monetizing Ecological Benefits and Benefits to Materials and Structures

Once changes in ecological service flows have been identified and quantified, analysts
can use a number of valuation methods to monetize the benefits of a regulation. The four
primary methods for monetizing ecological benefits are

•	hedonic property value models,

•	travel cost models,

•	expressed preference methods, and

•	market models.

Table 7-1 shows the categories of benefits for which each of these valuation methods is most
applicable. Each of these methods is briefly described below.

Hedonic Property Value Models. As noted above, hedonic pricing theory maintains
that the housing market functions as a market for environmental quality insofar as
environmental quality is a characteristic of the property being purchased or of the community
in which the property is located. Although often used to assess WTP to avoid environmental
health risks, hedonic property value models can be used to estimate the value individuals and
households place on the perceived amenity and recreation benefits provided by the property.
In addition, hedonic methods could conceivably be used to estimate housing damages related
to pollutant exposure; however, these methods have not been used for this purpose to date.

Travel Cost Models. Travel cost models have become a common method in the
economics literature for estimating the benefits of environmental improvements to recreators.
For example, these models can be used to estimate anglers' WTP to reduce toxic
contamination of a water body that otherwise would be subject to a fish consumption advisory
(see, for example, Montgomery and Needelman, 1997). Most often, travel cost models take
the form of a discrete-choice model known as a random utility model (RUM) in which a
recreator's choice among a set of unique recreation sites is modeled as a function of the

7-18


-------
Section 7 — Framework for Quantitative Benefits Analysis

Table 7-1. Applicability of Valuation Methods to Assess Categories of Ecological
Benefits

Aesthetic	Passive	Reduced

and Other	Use and	Damage to	Agricultural

Amenity	Recreation Nonuse	Materials and	Productivity

Benefits	Benefits Benefits	Structures	Gains

Hedonic Property	\/	\/

Value Models

Travel Cost Models	^	^

Expressed	^	^	^

Preference Methods

Market Models	^	^

characteristics of that site, including environmental quality. Because these models assume that
the cost of reaching each site is a function of travel and time costs, researchers can exploit
observed differences between travel distance and environmental quality to estimate the
monetary value of each site characteristic.

Expressed Preference Methods. Analysts use two primary expressed preference
methods to estimate the value of improvements in ecological systems. These include CV
studies and conjoint analyses. The characteristics of these methods are described in
Section 7.2.3.1, but it is important to note that only expressed preference methods can be
used to estimate nonuse values. Examples of CV studies used to estimate the value of
environmental improvements are Krutilla (1967) and Kopp (1992).

Market Models. Market models can be used to assess the impact of changes in
ecological services on both producers and consumers of market goods that rely on these
services. Producers often use natural resources as inputs into the production of goods and
services. To the extent that the quality of a natural resource such as groundwater is affected
by regulations designed to reduce the ambient concentrations of pollutants in groundwater, so
too will the cost and mix of inputs. These changes in the input mix and production costs can
be modeled using a firm's cost and factor demand functions. The resulting market supply
function can be coupled with the demand for the good or service being produced to determine
changes in producer and consumer surpluses. In addition, when the market good of interest is

7-19


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

an agricultural commodity, changes in increases in crop yield related to decreases in ambient
pollutant concentrations can be directly analyzed by estimating changes in consumer and
producer surpluses in the market for that commodity.

7.2.3.3 Benefit Values per Unit of Emissions

Often, the effect of a regulation on ambient concentrations of pollutants cannot be
easily determined. Likewise, it may be difficult to estimate the dose-response relationship or
concentration-response relationship needed to quantify the effect of a regulation on
environmental service flows. As an alternative to identifying, quantifying, and monetizing the
benefits of a regulation, it may be possible to forego the quantification step altogether and
directly relate changes in pollutant emissions to monetized environmental benefits. The two
most commonly studied types of pollutants are criteria air pollutants and greenhouse gases.
The results of these studies are presented below.

Criteria Air Pollutants. In developing its RIA for the recently proposed particulate
matter (PM) and ozone NAAQS, EPA estimated values for several impacts resulting from
reductions in ambient levels of ozone and particulate matter (PM). Although not entirely
comprehensive, these estimates include health values (mortality and morbidity), visibility
values, changes in agricultural productivity, and damages (soiling) to structures.

In a more recent analysis of its proposed PM and ozone rule for controlling emissions
from pulp and paper production (EPA, 1997a), EPA used the PM and ozone NAAQS rule
analysis to develop unit (i.e., per ton) estimates of the value of emissions reductions for
volatile organic compounds (VOCs), PM, and sulfur oxides (SOx). This was accomplished by
allocating the estimated total value of the NAAQS rule to each category of emissions and then
dividing these values by the respective emissions reduction estimates. The unit estimates and
their suggested application are shown in Table 7-2. Note: These estimates and their
applications are shown here for expository purposes only. Future analyses using the benefit-
per-unit-of-emissions approach should consider estimates most appropriate for the regulated
pollutant of interest.

Greenhouse Gas Emissions. The global warming impacts of greenhouse gas emissions
have been widely studied over the last decade. These include impacts on agricultural
production, sea level rise, biological diversity, fresh water supplies, and human health. The

7-20


-------
Section 7 — Framework for Quantitative Benefits Analysis

Table 7-2. Examples of Estimated Value per Mg for Selected Pollutants (1996$)

Pollutant

Location

Estimate

Benefit/Mg

Application

voc



Low estimate

$588

Apply only to VOC emissions reductions
estimated for areas with ozone concentrations
that would potentially violate the ozone NAAQS





High estimate

$2,656

Apply to all VOC emissions reduction

PM





$12,992

Apply to all PM emissions reductions

so2

Eastern U.S.

Low estimate

$5,834

Apply to all S02 emissions impacts estimated for
eastern mills





High estimate

$12,921

Apply to all S02 emissions impacts estimated for
eastern mills



Western U.S.

Low estimate

$4,221

Apply to all S02 emissions impacts estimated for
western mills





High estimate

$5,035

Apply to all S02 emissions impacts estimated for
western mills

Source: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. November 1997a. "Benefits-Transfer Analysis for Pulp and
Paper." OAQPS Staff Paper. Research Triangle Park, NC: OAQPS.

range of uncertainty associated with estimates of these impacts is generally quite large, and
relatively few of these studies have attempted to measure these impacts in monetary terms.
Nevertheless, a few studies do exist that provide order-of-magnitude estimates of monetary
damages per unit of greenhouse gas emissions. Table 7-3 summarizes a number of these
estimates. Most of these studies have used focused primarily on the global costs of sea level
rise and damages to agriculture, although the later studies include more complex models of
the interactions between economic activity and climate changes and have included estimates of
nonmarket impacts. It must be emphasized that these estimates are preliminary and are very
sensitive to the assumptions and features of the respective models, such as the climate change
model used, the discount rate used (usually between 2 percent and 6 percent), the time frame
selected, and the future economic growth rates assumed.

As with all benefits transfers, analysts should exercise caution when using estimates of
the benefits per unit of emissions in an economic analysis of an air regulation. In particular,
analysts should clearly identify the benefits categories to which these values apply. Analysts
should also describe the methods used in the original empirical studies to estimate these

7-21


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Table 7-3. Estimates of the Global Social Costs of Greenhouse Gas Emissions

Study

Chemical

Chemical
Name

Units

Range

Average

Time
Period
Covered

Nordhaus (1991a
andb)

C02

Carbon dioxide

$/tc

a

7.3

1991-2030

Ayers & Walter
(1991)

co2

Carbon dioxide

$/tc

30-35



2001-2010

Nordhaus (1992)

co2

Carbon dioxide

$/tc

5.3 - 10

7.68

1991-2030

Peck & Teisberg
(1993)

co2

Carbon dioxide

$/tc

10-22

15

1991-2030

Fankhauser (1994)

co2

Carbon dioxide

$/tc

20.3 -27.8

24.05

1991-2030

Fankhauser (1994)

ch4

Methane

$/tCH4

108.0- 176.0

141.25

1991-2030

Fankhauser (1994)

n2o

Nitrous oxide

$/tN20

2,895.0-4,489.0

3666.0

1991-2030

Fankhauser &
Pearce (1994)

co2

Carbon dioxide

$/tc

a

20.4



Fankhauser &
Pearce (1994)

N

Nitrogen
emitted as
nitrous oxide

$/Kg



2.94



Fankhauser &
Pearce (1994)

ch4

Methane

$/tCH4

a

110.0



Note: All units are metric tons unless otherwise noted.
a Data or range not available.

benefits and the methods by which these study results were translated into benefit values per
unit of emissions. In addition, analysts should note the magnitude of emissions reductions
estimated in the original study and the corresponding range of emissions reductions expected
to result from the rule in question. It is important to consider that, at the margin, the effects
of emissions reductions may differ depending on the baseline level of emissions, and the
magnitude of the planned emissions reduction. Finally, analysts should consider the
population affected by emissions reductions in the original study and the population expected
to be affected by the rule in question. It may be necessary to adjust the per-unit benefits to
reflect such differences. For a more detailed discussion of benefits transfer, see Section 7.3.

7-22


-------
Section 7 — Framework for Quantitative Benefits Analysis

7.3 Benefits Transfer

Monetizing the benefits of a regulation typically involves using benefits transfer; that
is, applying monetary values estimated in existing empirical studies to assess the value of a
quantified effect in a different study. In practice, this approach typically involves searching
the relevant empirical literature to identify existing studies that value effects similar to those in
which the analyst is interested. For example, if an analyst is evaluating the benefits of a
regulation for which the primary benefit is X premature deaths avoided, then the analyst will
want to identify studies that have estimated the values of a premature death avoided (i.e., the
VSL saved).

Once a relevant study (or studies) has (have) been identified, the analyst will need to
apply the results found in the study to his or her own economic analysis. In general, this can
be done in one of two ways:

•	by applying per-unit value estimates from the existing literature to the quantified
effects in the regulatory analysis, or

•	by using the functional form and parameter estimates presented in the existing
literature, along with data describing the population affected by the regulation, to
derive a new set of value estimates specific to the regulation.

The first approach (value transfer) is the simpler of the two methods; however, if the
analyst chooses this approach, he or she must use caution in identifying the empirical study (or
studies) to be used. In particular, to ensure that the results of the benefits transfer are
defensible, the analyst must ensure that the commodity valued in the existing study is
comparable to the identified benefit of the regulation and that the study population over which
the existing value estimate was derived is sufficiently similar to the population that will receive
the regulatory benefit.

The second approach (functional transfer) alleviates a majority of the problems
associated with specifying the appropriate population. For example, if the existing literature
defines WTP to avoid a premature death as a specific function of income or age, then this
relationship can be used to more accurately specify a value estimate for the regulatory context.
If the population affected by a rule has a high average income or age, then the benefit function
can be used to estimate WTP conditional on these characteristics. Compared to using an
unconditional unit-value estimate from existing studies, this approach should provide a value

7-23


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

that more accurately reflects the affected population's WTP. Even though the functional
transfer approach enables the analyst to tailor the empirical results to the specific population
of interest, the analyst must still ensure that the effect being analyzed in the existing literature
resembles, as closely as possible, the effect of interest to the analyst.

Analysts applying benefits transfer techniques are referred to the March 1992 edition
of Water Resources Research for a thorough discussion of the advantages and criticisms of
using benefits transfer.

7-24


-------
Section 8 — General Methodological Issues

SECTION 8
GENERAL METHODOLOGICAL ISSUES

Several methodological issues are fundamental to any EA. Addressing these issues is
necessary to ensure that the benefits and costs of a regulatory option can be directly compared
with each other and with the benefits and costs of other regulatory options. This section
focuses on four general methodological issues:

•	specifying the time period of analysis,

•	specifying a baseline for analysis,

•	discounting benefits and costs, and

•	addressing uncertainty.

8.1 Specifying the Time Period of Analysis

By their nature, most regulations impose costs and confer benefits for many years. In
fact, the intent of a regulatory action is usually to correct a current problem indefinitely. As a
result, EAs of regulatory actions must be designed to facilitate the comparison of regulatory
benefits and costs over time. However, because analytical resources are not unlimited and
because the accuracy of cost and benefit estimates decreases for values far in the future, it is
often necessary and appropriate to limit that time period to a finite time period. There is
frequently no clear basis for determining the appropriate time period for analysis. The time
period must allow the analyst to capture any specific identified changes expected to occur
over time, and it must be applied consistently to the calculation of both benefits and costs.

It is common practice to calculate the costs of a regulatory option over the period of
time corresponding to the expected useful lifetime of capital equipment purchased to comply
with the rule. For example, if the capital equipment purchased as a result of the rule has an
expected useful life of 15 years, an analyst might calculate the expected costs of the rule over
a 15-year period. For consistency, benefits should be calculated over the same 15-year
period.

8-1


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

It is often not necessary to extend the time period of analysis beyond the length of a
single capital life cycle. In most cases the estimated benefits and costs of distant years will not
differ substantially from those of the years immediately following the effective date of the
regulation. Also, it is often difficult to predict factors, such as the development of new
technologies, changes in demand, or changes in behavior patterns, that could cause substantial
changes in costs or benefits over time. Therefore, the benefits and costs estimated for the first
several years will typically represent all that can be said in the analysis regarding the impacts
of the rule for the indefinite future.

Some of the benefits resulting from actions taken during the capital life cycle,
however, may not be realized during the time period of analysis. For example, if the cost
analysis calculates costs over a 15-year period, the benefits analysis should include any
benefits realized during Years 1 through 15 as well as any benefits realized after Year 15
attributable to actions taken to comply with the regulation during Years 1 through 15.

Benefits realized in Year 20 should be counted if they are related to compliance actions taken
in Year 15 or earlier; they should not be counted if they are related to actions taken in Year 16
or later. In general, benefits realized in the future should be counted in the analysis if they can
be directly related to actions taken during the period of analysis used for estimating costs.

For some regulations, using the equipment cycle criterion to select the analysis time
period may be difficult to apply either practically or conceptually. From the practical
standpoint, a regulation might require the regulated entity to purchase multiple capital
equipment items, each having different service lives. In these cases, determination of the
appropriate capital cycle is a judgment call. In other cases, the capital cycle may be of limited
conceptual relevance. For instance, the required capital expenditure might simply involve a
one-time expenditure to change a production process, or it may involve the acceleration of
purchases that would be made as normal business practice (e.g., accelerated replacement of
equipment). Because both of these situations involve an initial expenditure of funds to
generate service flows over time, they are appropriately viewed as capital expenditures.
However, in contrast to the purchase of a specific piece of equipment, the "useful life" of the
one-time expenditure or accelerated expenditures is not as well defined.

An example of an OAQPS regulation in which useful life conceptual issues arise is the
architectural coatings rule (EPA, 1998b). That rule required some producers of architectural
coatings to reduce the content of volatile organic compounds (VOCs) by reformulating their
products. Reformulation—for the purposes of compliance—would presumably occur only

8-2


-------
Section 8 — General Methodological Issues

once. In that regard, the useful life of this initial action is not necessarily confined to a finite
period, as would be the case for equipment that physically depreciates and must be replaced at
some point in the future. An alternative view is that reformulation is a normal business
practice and that the rule requires some producers to simply expedite that process. The EIA
prepared for the architectural coatings presents a variety of different service life
interpretations for the reformulation requirement and evaluates their cost implications.

One way to minimize the confusion surrounding the capital cycle issue is to convert all
costs and benefits to their annualized equivalents. This does not entirely circumvent the
service life issue. The analyst must still select a service life over which to annualize any capital
requirements. However, it ensures that costs and benefits will be compared on a consistent
time frame basis and does not require the arbitrary selection of a multiyear time period for
analysis. Moreover, issues of economic significance addressed in various statutes and EOs
(e.g., UMRA and EO 12866) often use annual impact as a criterion.

Discounting may also provide some perspective on the appropriate time period of
analysis. In particular, once discounted future benefits or costs become negligible, little is
gained by extending the analysis further into the future. It is important to note, however, that
this method of determining the time period of analysis is highly sensitive to the discount rate
used. Discounting methods and rates are discussed in more detail later in this section.

8.2 Specifying a Baseline for Analysis

To develop estimates of the benefits and costs of a regulatory option, the analyst must
project what the world would look like if the provisions of the rule are enacted—the post-
regulation state of the world. To clearly identify the effects of the rule, the analyst must then
characterize the world in the absence of the regulation and compare the two states of the
world. The expected state of the world without the regulation is referred to as the baseline.
Although many issues must be decided when establishing a baseline for use in an EA, a 1997
EPA policy briefing provides recommendations that should apply to all baseline decisions
(EPA, 1997i). In particular, the policy briefing recommends that analysts should

•	use a realistic set of assumptions about expected future conditions in the absence
of the program;

•	use a consistent baseline in all parts of the EA;

8-3


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

•	identify those assumptions that most affect benefit and cost estimates and
concentrate scarce analytical resources on refining and exploring these
assumptions;

•	emphasize a single baseline for clarity of presentation but present analyses with a
range of relevant baselines when appropriate; and

•	clearly describe the assumptions underlying the specification of the baseline,
measurement of the baseline, and the reasons why the chosen specification is
appropriate.

According to OMB's guidance for conducting EAs, "the baseline should be the best
assessment of the way the world would look absent the proposed regulation" (OMB, 1996).
Developing such an assessment has many components, including

•	forecasting economic activity in the absence of the regulation;

•	assessing the rate of compliance with existing regulations;

•	anticipating future regulatory actions by other Federal agencies, by other offices
within the Agency, and by State, local, and tribal governments;

•	anticipating the effects of nonregulatory programs; and

•	developing a starting point for the baseline.

Each of these components is discussed in more detail below.

8.2.1 Forecasting Economic Activity in the Absence of the Regulation

Typically, for OAQPS regulations, forecasting economic activity centers on predicting
the levels of production and consumption of the regulated product in a world without the
regulation.1 To generate accurate cost and benefit estimates, it is necessary to incorporate
changes in production expected during the period of analysis into the baseline scenario.

Analysts use three basic approaches to specify baseline production:

•	Project changes in production over time—Obtaining or developing very specific
estimates of changes in production levels over time may be possible. Alternatively,
it may be possible to apply constant rates of change to current production

'Although production and consumption can differ by changes in the stock of inventories, it is assumed for the
purpose of this discussion that production equals consumption and the change in inventories is zero.

8-4


-------
Section 8 — General Methodological Issues

estimates (e.g., current production totals 1 million units and is expected to grow at
3 percent annually). However, this approach can impose significant computational
burden on the analyst and may not yield a great deal of information.

•	Estimate current production and hold constant—In many cases, changes in
production are difficult to predict or do not have much impact on the conclusions
of the analysis. For example, if both benefits and costs for all options are directly
proportional to the level of production, the level of production will influence the
magnitude of the cost and benefit estimates but will have no impact on the ranking
of options or on the determination of whether they offer positive net benefits. In
such cases, forecasting changes in production should not be necessary.

•	Estimate "representative-year "production and hold constant—Even if the level
of production is expected to change over time, it may be possible to develop an
estimate for a single year that represents some weighted average of the level of
production over the entire period of analysis. Alternatively, it may be reasonable
to project production levels for up to 5 years into the future and use the fifth-year
estimate as the expected level of production in the remaining periods. This
approach combines the advantages of the first two approaches. In particular, it
will account for changes in production over time and therefore approximate the
correct magnitude of benefits and costs without the need for separate year-by-year
calculations.

8.2.2 Assessing the Rate of Compliance with Existing Regulations

Often a planned regulatory action is intended to modify an existing Agency rule. In
such cases, the baseline must incorporate some assumption regarding the rate of compliance
with existing rules. The determination of a baseline must also include some assessment of
expected future compliance with existing rules. The primary reason for establishing current
compliance is to better gauge the likely effectiveness (benefits) of the proposed regulation as
well as the costs.

Although there is no stated Agency policy regarding the treatment of current
compliance in establishing the baseline, most EAs assume full compliance with existing
regulations. In reality, overcompliance and noncompliance exist. For example, in certain
industries air pollutant emissions are below the maximum level allowed by existing emissions
standards. In other cases, plants may be out of compliance with emissions standards, and their
noncompliance is undetected because of variability in enforcement efforts across states. The
question the analyst must consider in developing a baseline is simply whether the full-
compliance assumption makes sense for this analysis. For example, when the purpose of a

8-5


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

rule is to clarify enforcement or monitoring procedures, assuming full compliance with
existing regulations may understate the benefits of the regulation if its primary purpose is to
improve compliance with existing regulations. Likewise, if the purpose of the rule is to
strengthen existing requirements in an industry that is performing better than the current rule
requires, assuming compliance with the current standards would overstate both benefits and
costs.

Realizing that the full-compliance assumption simplifies an analysis and that
determining actual levels of compliance can often be costly, a 1997 EPA policy briefing on
selecting a baseline for analysis recommends using actual compliance estimates when
establishing a baseline for the following types of regulations:

•	procedural, enforcement, and monitoring rules;

•	rules strengthening current standards when noncompliance is common among
regulated entities;

•	rules loosening current standards (deregulation) when noncompliance is common
among regulated entities; and

•	any rulemaking undertaken when the performance of regulated entities exceeds
current requirements (EPA, 1997i).

8.2.3 Anticipating Future Regulatory Actions by Other Federal Agencies, by Other

Offices within the Agency, and by State, Local, and Tribal Governments

In the United States, regulatory authority is shared not only by a number of agencies
within the Federal government, but also among State, local, and tribal governments.
Sometimes the regulatory programs of these entities overlap. For example, emissions from
pesticide production facilities may be regulated under the CAA, but the pesticide products
themselves are regulated under the Federal Insecticide, Fungicide, and Rodenticide Act
(FIFRA), as chemical substances under TSCA, and as food additives under the Food, Drug,
and Cosmetic Act (FDCA). Therefore, any forecast of future conditions ideally considers the
potential regulatory actions of other agencies or levels of government.

In establishing a baseline, it is reasonable to assume that previously promulgated
regulations and regulations that will be promulgated prior to the effective date of the rule
being analyzed are in full effect at the time of the analysis. The potential impacts of rules in
earlier stages of development are more difficult to assess. The two most practical methods for

8-6


-------
Section 8 — General Methodological Issues

addressing these potential actions are to discuss rules that may affect the baseline qualitatively
and to assume that the effective dates required by statute or listed in the Unified Regulatory
Agenda will be met and incorporate the expected impacts of these rules in the baseline.

8.2.4	Anticipating Nonregulatory Factors

Over time, both industrial and household behavior may change in a way that affects
output and pollution levels for reasons completely independent of any regulatory requirement.
For example, firms may also modify their behavior and resulting pollutant loadings to avoid
litigation. As judicial decisions clarify or redefine property rights, polluting firms may adjust
their behavior to reduce emissions; reduce exposure; or increase safety for their workers, their
consumers, or the surrounding community. One factor causing changes in behavior may be
the Agency's nonregulatory initiatives. For example, information provided by EPA's Design
for the Environment program may result in firms choosing EPA-recommended equipment
over other alternatives that would result in higher pollutant emissions.

The effects of nonregulatory factors are often ignored in developing a baseline for EAs
usually because of limited time and resources available for conducting an EA. Ideally,
however, these effects should be included, to the extent feasible, in the baseline. At a
minimum, nonregulatory factors that could reasonably be expected to influence the baseline
should be discussed qualitatively.

8.2.5	Developing a Starting Point for the Baseline

Once the fact that an agency is considering a regulatory action becomes public,
households and firms may begin to adjust their behavior in anticipation of the rule. As a result
of such preemptive actions, the state of the world may change prior to promulgation of the
rule. The question then becomes whether these changes should be included in the baseline or
considered an effect of the rule.

Whether actions taken by potentially regulated entities after a pending rule becomes
known, but prior to rule promulgation, should be considered part of the baseline depends on
the answer to a hypothetical question. If these actions would not likely continue if, for some
reason, the rule is not promulgated, then the actions themselves are viewed as being caused by
the rule and should therefore should not be included in the baseline. If, instead, these actions
would likely persist even in the absence of a final rulemaking, then these changes cannot easily
be attributed to the rule itself and should be considered part of the baseline. If an activity is

8-7


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

included in the baseline, then its costs and its benefits should not be attributed to the rule in
the EA.

If the analyst believes that behavioral changes induced by knowledge of the regulatory
action should be considered an effect of the rulemaking, the baseline should begin at the date
corresponding to the first public notice of the rulemaking. In the case of a regulatory action
required by statute, this would be the date the legislative action requiring the rule becomes
law. When a regulation is a result of an Agency initiative, independent of a statutory deadline,
knowledge of the proposed action typically becomes public by official notice (e.g., ANPR or
NPRM) in the FR or through the rule's inclusion in the Unified Regulatory Agenda. If,
instead, the analyst believes that actions taken in anticipation of the rule should not be
considered a direct result of the rulemaking, then these anticipatory actions should be included
in the baseline. Then the baseline should begin either at the date of promulgation or the
effective date of the rule.

8.3 Discounting Benefits and Costs

The manner in which the benefits and costs of a regulatory action are discounted to
account for differences in their timing is perhaps the most contentious of all methodological
issues in the economic analysis of environmental policy. The reasons for this are both simple
and complex. The simplicity derives from the fact that the mere mechanics of discounting can
have a decisive impact on whether benefit-cost results favor a particular action because
environmental regulation often involves costs now and benefits later. When discounting is
used, the future benefits decline in comparison to the present costs. When a higher discount
rate is used, the results are less favorable for the action generating the future benefits. The
complexity derives from the fact that the decision to discount future events involves implicit
acceptance of certain political and economic philosophies, and the selection of an appropriate
discount rate requires consideration of what some policymakers might perceive as complex
economic concepts.

With the controversy and complexity of discounting as background, the Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management (JEEM) in 1990 devoted an entire issue to the
conceptual, empirical, and practical considerations of the discounting issue. This issue of
JEEM helped elucidate many of the issues, but it did not—nor did it intend to—arrive at a set
of recommended rules for applying discounting methods in environmental policy evaluation.
In 1996, EPA convened the Economic Consistency Workgroup. This workgroup


-------
Section 8 — General Methodological Issues

commissioned a series of "White Papers" to address a number of methodological issues,
including social discounting. These white papers will provide the basis for the issuance in
1998 of an agencywide guidance document for economic analysis. The white paper on
discounting is an important reference point for the current document.2

Abstracting from these earlier and ongoing assessments of discounting methods, the
following discussion addresses discounting considerations in economic analysis of OAQPS
regulations. The issue is addressed by first describing why discounting is necessary to
evaluate both private decisions and public policies. Then, the mechanics of discounting in net
present value methods are presented. The discussion then focuses more specifically on which
discount rate is appropriate for annualizing capital costs, and it presents prescriptions other
researchers have made for costing methods that are consistent with principles of welfare
economics. Economists have recently defined the openness of capital markets as a key
determinant of the aggregate social cost of a policy intervention. That issue is addressed here
both in the context of aggregate social benefit-cost analysis found in EAs and the more
narrowly scoped assessment of impacts found in an EIA. The discussion concludes with a
recommendation for capital cost discounting in economic analysis of OAQPS policies.

8.3.1 Basic Considerations in Discounting

Discounting is the process by which the different time streams of benefits and costs of
a particular action can be placed on a comparable basis. Discounting is relevant for private
consumption and investment decisions and therefore is relevant, in a somewhat more
complicated manner, for public decisions that affect consumption and investment patterns of
individuals affected by the decision.

8.3.1.1 Discounting and Private Decisions

In this context, private decisions refer to choices made by households and firms that
affect the allocation of their own resources over time. The general premise is that both
households and firms are not indifferent to the time pattern of resource allocation. Both
prefer to either consume (households) or receive profits (firms) and income (households)

2The white papers and agency guidance document are, at the time of this writing, evolving documents. Latest
versions can be obtained from the Economy and Environment Division of EPA's Office of Policy (formerly
Office of Policy, Planning, and Evaluation).

8-9


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

sooner rather than later. There are two basic models demonstrating time preferences for
consumption and investment.

Consumption. For ease of presentation, the term household is used synonymously
with the individual consumer. While some models distinguish between individual and group
(household) decisions, those distinctions are not addressed here.

Households are typically viewed as seeking to maximize their utility over time. Utility
(U) is dependent on the consumption of goods and services (C):

U = U(C)	(8.1)

More consumption yields higher utility (i.e., <9U/<9C > 0). The need to discount can be
evaluated by considering consumption over two time periods. This evaluation can be
extended to more time periods without loss of generality. The two-period objective function
is specified as follows:

V=U(C0) + U(C1)/(l+p)	(8.2)

where V is the present value of the utility gained from consumption in the current (0) and next
(1) period and p is the single-period discount rate for consumption. Generally, p > 0,
reflecting the notion that a unit of consumption deferred to the next period is valued less by
the household than if the unit were consumed presently. In this context, p is often referred to
as the marginal rate of time preference or the consumption rate of interest. Therefore, when
households evaluate the consequences of an action that alters consumption patterns over time,
for instance, by investing (reducing consumption) today to generate future benefits (increased
consumption) in the future, they will generally require more consumption in the future to
compensate for a given level of foregone consumption today.

Investment. Investment is the process of expending funds today to purchase an asset
(capital) that generates a stream of future income. Although asset characteristics differ across
households and firms, the underlying concept of an opportunity cost of the investment is
relevant across all asset types. Consider an investment requiring I0 of funds today that returns
income of Yx a year from now. The net present value (NPV) of this action can be expressed

Z = Yj/(l+r) - I0	(8.3)

where Z is the NPV of the investment and r is the single-period discount rate. Generally, r >
0, reflecting the notion that income received next period is valued less than current income.

8-10


-------
Section 8 — General Methodological Issues

This discount factor, r, is conceptually distinct from the consumption rate, p, referenced
above, in that it reflects the opportunity cost of capital committed to the investment rather
than the disutility of deferring consumption. The reason to discount future income streams
generated by an investment is that committing funds to that particular asset requires foregoing
income streams from alternative investments. The term, r, reflects the rate of return on
alternative assets. Thus, the I0 worth of funds allocated to this investment could generate a
return of I0(l+r) next period if invested elsewhere. Therefore, the expected income next
period, Yx, must be discounted by the factor (1+r) to appropriately value the investment.
Having performed the appropriate discounting, the investment should be undertaken if the
NPV, Z, is positive.

Another way to characterize the situation is in terms of capital's rental cost. Investing
ties up capital in the ownership of the asset. By not allowing these funds to flow elsewhere,
the capital is "rented" in the form of this particular asset. Ignoring the issues of asset service
life, depreciation, and capital gains, the rental cost of capital is r*I0, also referred to as the
annualized cost of capital.

Summary Point. The motivation for discounting in private decisions is similar,
whether the decisionmakers are households or firms and whether the economic activity is
consumption or investment. In all cases, the future is discounted relative to the present.
Households discount future consumption because they prefer present consumption. Firms and
households discount the future returns from an investment because the capital tied up in the
investment could be invested elsewhere. The mechanics of discounting are essentially the
same in both situations, with the consumption rate of time interest (p) determining the value
of consumption streams and the opportunity cost of capital (r) determining the value of
investment streams. However, as discussed below, these two discount rates will, in general,
differ. Therefore, discounting methods must account for these differences.

8.3.1.2 Discounting and Public Policy Decisions

While the private decisions just described are driven by the benefits and costs accruing
to the individual household or firm making the decision, public policy decisions must account
for the benefits and costs accruing to the entire society, empowering the public
decisionmakers. Hence, the term social benefit-cost analysis (SBCA) is used for the types of
public decisions faced by EPA.

8-11


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Assuming that public policies have the objective of raising society's welfare, the time
preferences of that society are relevant to the benefit-cost criterion for public policy analysis.
As described above, people generally demonstrate a preference for current consumption over
future consumption. Moreover, investing funds in a particular project foregoes an income
stream generated by another use. Therefore, policies that require investment and alter the
time pattern of consumption must account for these temporal factors, hence the need to
discount in SBCA.

Economic welfare measures are generally derived from the consumption of goods and
services. As a result, SBCA should be ultimately translated to corresponding effects on
society's consumption patterns over time. Differences in consumption across time periods can
be compared after adjusting for the consumption rate of interest, which is the rate of return at
which individuals are willing to trade off current consumption for future consumption.

At this point, the distinction between the benefits and costs of a regulatory action is
important. The appropriate welfare measure for benefits is the amount that parties are willing
to pay to obtain these benefits. An example might be the amount parties are willing to pay to
reduce the population risk of cancer by 0.1 percent. For all intents and purposes, this can be
viewed as a consumption equivalent, and the multiperiod consumption model presented above
applies. Then, benefits that accrue over time can be compared and aggregated using the
consumption rate of interest.

The social cost of a regulatory action is the value of opportunities foregone by
allocating resources to the activity. Society could have otherwise used the funds for current
consumption or invested those funds in other economically productive activities (thereby
enhancing future consumption). Once costs are expressed in consumption equivalents, they
can be discounted at the same rate as benefits. Special discounting issues related to the social
opportunity cost of mandated capital expenditures and its connection to the capital cost
estimated in an EIA are addressed in more detail below.

The need to discount in benefit-cost analysis of public policies can be summarized as
follows:

1.	Environmental regulation implicitly aspires to raise social welfare.

2.	Social welfare, as modeled in economics, is determined by consumption of market
and nonmarket goods and services; therefore, the effects of a particular policy or

8-12


-------
Section 8 — General Methodological Issues

regulation should be transformed to consumption equivalents to evaluate its
welfare consequences.

3.	The evaluation of the social welfare consequences of policies that affect current
and future patterns of consumption should account for the fact that individual
members of society are generally observed to value current consumption more than
future consumption.

4.	Discounting is the mechanism by which these preferences are imposed on social
welfare measures of policy options.

The two-stage discounting procedure can be used to discount benefits and costs of a
regulatory action in a theoretically consistent manner.

8.3.2 The Two-Stage Discounting Procedure3

The shadow price of capital approach calls for converting all mandated private capital
costs to annualized consumption equivalents by using an estimate of the pre-tax private rate of
return to generate the annual stream of costs (foregone consumption) (Kolb and Scheraga,
1990).4 This cost stream can then be converted to a present value using the consumption rate
of time preference. The cost value can then be compared to the present value of benefits,
which is computed using the consumption rate of time preference exclusively. This method is
applied by using the two-stage discounting method discussed in this section.

The two-stage discounting procedure uses two different discount rates (see Scheraga,
1989). This approach is a variant of the shadow price of capital approach in that capital costs
are adjusted upward to reflect the social cost of displaced investment before benefits and costs
are discounted at the consumption rate of interest. The steps involved in the two-stage
discounting process are as follows:

3In October 1992, OMB issued a revised version of its Circular A-94, which contains guidance on discounting
in regulatory analyses. OMB's 1996 economic analysis guidance defers to the 1992 Circular. EPA's
Office of Policy continues to examine this issue through the development of its new EA guidance
document, and changes in EPA's recommended discounting methods may be forthcoming.

4The discount rate reflecting the opportunity cost of capital, as specified in OMB Circular A-94, is currently
estimated to be 7 percent. This represents the average of the returns on low-yielding capital investments,
such as housing, and the returns on high-yielding investments, such as corporate capital. OMB's EA
guidance recommends using the opportunity cost of capital for discounting in EAs of regulations (OMB,
1996).

8-13


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

1.	Annualize capital costs over the expected lifetime of the capital equipment using
the opportunity cost of capital. In ISEG, 7 percent is typically used as the
opportunity cost of capital (consistent with OMB Circular A-94). After
annualizing capital costs, add annual noncapital costs to annualized capital costs to
yield total annual costs.

2.	Discount the stream of annualized costs at the consumption rate of interest. In
general, this rate will be lower than the opportunity cost of capital. As described
below, 3 percent is commonly used for the consumption rate of interest. The
stream of benefits is also discounted using this rate.

These procedures result in present value cost and benefit estimates that can be directly
compared with one another and with other present value estimates.

To illustrate how the two-stage discounting procedure works, consider the following
example.5 A regulatory option will impose $20 million in capital costs during the first year for
equipment that is expected to last 15 years. In addition, there will be $5 million in annual
operating costs, also beginning in the first year. Benefits of $8 million will be realized each
year over the 15-year time period. The question is whether the $8 million in annual benefits
exceed the costs.

Stage 1: Annualize Costs

To estimate the present value of the costs of the regulation over the useful life of the
capital, it is first necessary to annualize the capital costs, using the opportunity cost of capital.
Annualization is the calculation of the value that, if paid out in equal annual amounts over a
specified period and discounted, would be equal to the present value.6 Annualization is the
calculation of the value x that solves Eq. (8.4).

T	X	X	X

I - 	 + 	 + ... + 		(8 4)

0+i) (1+i)2 (1+i)"	K }

5This example is borrowed directly from the document, Guidance on the Preparation of Economic Analyses in
OPPT, Office of Pollution Prevention and Toxics, Economic Analysis and Policy Branch, September
1998c.

6This is identical to the types of calculations made to determine mortgage payments or car payments.

8-14


-------
Section 8 — General Methodological Issues

where

I	=	the present value of the capital investment,

x	=	the annualized value,

i	=	the discount rate, and

n	=	the number of years over which the value is annualized.

Note that the annualized costs are evaluated as if they occur at the end of each year. The
annualized capital cost can be computed by manipulating Eq. (8.4) to solve for x as follows

T i(l +i)

x = I —-	-—	(8.5)

(1 +i)n - 1	V ;

In this example, the annualized cost of I = $20 million over n = 15 years at i = 7 percent is
approximately $2.2 million. For purposes of calculating the total annual costs of the
regulation, the annualized capital cost of $2.2 million is added to the $5 million in costs
incurred each year for a total annual cost of $7.2 million.

Stage 2: Compute "Consumption Equivalent" Present Value of Costs and Benefits

In the second stage, the annual values estimated in the first stage are converted into a
present value, using the consumption rate of interest. This calculation can be performed using
Eq. (8.4), with the following values: x = $7.2 million (total annual cost), i = 0.03 (the
consumption rate of interest), n = 15 years. The present value of an annual cost of
$7.2 million over 15 years at a 3 percent discount rate is $85.9 million.

To calculate the present value of benefits, the same procedure described above for the
second stage of the cost calculation is used. In this example, the annual benefits are $8 million
per year. The present value of a 15-year annual stream of benefits, using a 3 percent discount
rate, is $95.5 million. This regulatory option would therefore yield positive present value net
benefits of $9.6 million ($95.5 million benefits minus $85.9 million costs) over the period of
analysis.

It is important to note that in this example the calculation of present value benefits and
costs is not necessary to determine the correct decision. Once the annualized total costs are

8-15


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

estimated, enough information is revealed to determine the annualized net benefits of the
regulation. In cases such as this, in which both benefits and costs can be expressed at a
constant rate over the same time period, calculating the present value of net benefits is
redundant. Instead, annual costs (with capital costs annualized using the opportunity cost of
capital) can be compared with annual benefits. If annual benefits exceed annual costs in each
year, then the net benefits of the rule will be positive.

If, however, benefits vary across years or accrue over a time period different from the
one in which costs are incurred, the full calculation is necessary to determine whether the net
benefit condition is met. In such cases, the analyst will typically calculate the present values of
both the cost and benefit streams. Alternatively, the present value of the stream of benefits
can be calculated and then annualized over the time period in which the costs are imposed to
facilitate an annual comparison.

Regardless of whether costs are expressed on an annualized or present value basis, it is
critical that

•	any calculations make proper use of discounting procedures and rates to arrive at
the correct annualized or present value, and

•	the same procedures be used to calculate benefits and costs when these values are
to be compared. In other words, if costs are expressed in annualized terms,
benefits should be expressed on the same basis.

8.3.3 Discounting Issues Deserving Further Attention: Nonmonetized Benefits and

Long Time Horizons

Although reviewing all the economic theory relating to the discounting of benefits is
beyond the scope of this economics manual, discounting nonmonetized benefits and benefits
accruing to future generations merits some further discussion.

As mentioned above, EPA guidelines indicate that benefits should be discounted using
the rate of time preference. It is important to note that both quantified and monetized benefits
should be discounted. On conceptual grounds, benefits that are quantified but not monetized
can be discounted in the same manner as monetized benefits. The absence of monetary values
simply means that nonmonetized benefits cannot be compared directly to monetized benefits
or costs. However, if these benefits are quantified by some nonmonetary metric (e.g.,
adverse health effects avoided) there is no reason, in principle, why future effects should not
be discounted relative to present effects. The underlying premise is that these quantified

8-16


-------
Section 8 — General Methodological Issues

effects positively affect utility, thereby carrying some (apparently unmeasurable) value society
is willing to pay. Thus, discounting these benefits is no less warranted than discounting
monetized benefits.

Discount rates essentially reflect choices revealed in credit markets by the current
generation. In some instances, however, the benefits of a regulatory action may accrue well
into the future (e.g., reducing the threat of catastrophic climate change). These situations
raise unique questions about intergenerational equity. Because the parties benefitting from
such regulations are not yet born, it is not clear whether a market-based rate of time
preference adequately incorporates the expected utilities of future generations.

Analysts disagree whether long time horizon problems merit special consideration.
Some economists and policy analysts argue that benefits accruing to future generations should
not be discounted at all. Others believe that intergenerational concerns can often be addressed
by using a social rate of time preference—the rate of time preference modified to reflect
intergenerational equity considerations (EPA, 1997j). The draft EPA white paper on
discounting suggests that when faced with a situation involving intergenerational concerns, the
analyst should acknowledge that both sides of this debate have merit and calculate the present
value of future benefit streams using both a zero discount rate (not discounting at all) and the
rate of time preference (effectively discounting all expected future benefits in the same way)
(Arnold, Sussman, and Deck, 1997). The analyst should refer to OP's forthcoming
Guidelines for Economic Analysis (referenced in Section 1) for further guidance on
discounting methods for long time horizon problems.

8.3.4 Discount Rates and the Capital Costs of the Regulation

The basic premise of the two-stage discounting method is that a different rate should
be used to annualize the capital costs of a regulation than is used to discount streams of
benefits and costs through time. In EIAs or EAs performed by ISEG, the selection of the rate
to annualize costs is at least as important, if not more so, than the rate used to compute
present values of the net benefits. This is particularly true when all costs (and/or benefits) are
computed on an annualized basis, as they are with many of the analyses performed in ISEG.
In those cases, the rate used to compute present values is moot, and the only discount rate
that matters is the rate used to annualize capital costs. As a result, the selection of the proper
rate to annualize capital costs is of paramount importance in ISEG analyses.

8-17


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

8.3.4.1 Conceptual Issues

Government can intervene to achieve public policy objectives in essentially two ways.
One is to use public funds to produce a good or service that the private sector cannot or does
not have the incentive to produce (e.g., national defense). The other is to mandate private
expenditures to achieve a public objective. The importance of distinguishing between public
programs and mandated private expenditures relates to the opportunity costs of the funds
spent on the activity. Although much of the discussion surrounding social discount rates
draws from examples of public expenditure (see Lind, 1990), mandated private expenditure is
relevant to the discussion of environmental regulation and is the point of departure here.

Sectoral us. Economywide Measures of Social Costs. Before proceeding, important
points must be made regarding factors that often complicate the dialogue on costs, economic
impacts, and social welfare. One is the need to distinguish between the social cost measured
in the economic sector directly affected by the regulation and the total social cost of a
regulation. Section 5 of this document demonstrates how to estimate social cost-based
measures (i.e., producer and consumer surplus) of the regulation in the directly affected
industries (markets). There may be differences between those measures and the "true" social
cost due to the indirect effect that changes in the regulated market might have on other
sectors of the economy. This issue has typically been viewed from a pragmatic standpoint.
Except in cases where the direct impacts in one market are extremely large and/or cut across
many sectors of the economy (e.g., climate change) it is usually acceptable to ignore the
muted indirect impacts in other markets and take the impacts in the directly affected markets
as the appropriate measure. When the impacts are too large to ignore, it may require the use
of general equilibrium modeling approaches to capture these impacts (e.g., Hazilla and Kopp,
1990). General equilibrium considerations are not addressed in the present discussion.

Instead, the key issues relate to the emerging literature on discount rates (as summarized in
the EPA White Paper), namely, that the assumption one has about corresponding effects in the
capital market determines the appropriate rate for estimating aggregate social costs.

This section continues with a discussion of methods for annualizing capital costs in a
typical EIA. The primary objective of an EIA is to estimate the magnitude of a regulation's
cost and the distribution of the burden of those costs among the producers and consumers in a
particular regulated industry. EIAs generally give a first-order approximation of the total
social cost of a regulation. The second part of the discussion considers factors that may
impart differences between the social costs estimated in an EIA and the "true" aggregate

8-18


-------
Section 8 — General Methodological Issues

social costs of a regulation. Of particular concern is the role that assumptions on the mobility
of capital may have on differences between these two estimates. Because the EIA is often the
basis for the cost estimate in a full SBCA required in an EA, the discussion attempts to
reconcile the two measures. This identifies the critical assumptions and parameters
determining their difference and allows the analyst or policymaker to choose between methods
based on the reasonableness of the underlying assumptions and parameters.

8.3.4.2 Estimating Capital Costs in Economic Impact Analysis

The CAA as amended requires that an EIA be performed to estimate the costs of a set
of pollution control responsibilities and to determine how those costs are distributed among
producers and consumers in the regulated industry. As part of an EA, the SBCA compares
the social costs of a regulation to its social benefits to help policymakers assess whether the
regulation is justified under the provisions of EO 12866—Regulatory Planning and Review.
As indicated in Section 2 of this document, EAs (SBCAs) are required only for regulations
deemed to be economically significant. Therefore, while many OAQPS regulations require an
EIA, relatively few lead to SBCAs (EAs). Nonetheless, it is important that EIAs generate
information that is transformable to a full SBCA. Specifically, the EIA should produce an
estimate of the social cost of a regulation that is theoretically consistent and therefore
comparable to estimates of social benefits, should the comparison be called for in a subsequent
SBCA.

Typically, the EIA is preceded by an analysis that estimates the cost of regulatory
compliance for each pollution source subject to the regulation. The pollution sources in the
analysis may constitute a full and exhaustive census of all facilities in the regulated industry or,
more likely, an array of model facilities or some combination of actual and model facilities.
Consistent with the goal of estimating the size and distribution of social costs among different
parties affected by the regulation, and given that the distribution of these costs is largely
determined by economic behavior, an EIA ideally employs an analytical framework that
captures the effect of the control responsibilities in a market setting. The modeling
mechanism for capturing these market effects is discussed in Section 5.

The firm that is faced with pollution control responsibilities will incur the cost of the
required capital equipment. Operating and maintenance (O&M) costs are ignored here to
focus on the capital discounting issue. The current discussion also ignores the need to
periodically replace the capital equipment and simply assumes that the service life of the

8-19


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

capital is infinite. As a consequence, the annualized cost of the capital purchase is rK where K
is the purchase price of the compliance capital and r is the firm's cost of capital. The cost of
capital represents what it must give up (annually) to make this capital purchase. This is either
the foregone opportunity to invest K worth of internal funds in another investment, to
distribute K worth of funds to shareholders, or to repay a party for lending it the funds to
invest K in pollution control. In any case, the cost of compliance capital reflects the rate of
return the funds can achieve in another use.

As indicated in Section 5, a market model can be constructed to simulate economic
behavior on the part of producers responding to compliance requirements and consumers
responding to any corresponding change in price. As a result, the burden will, in general, be
shared by producers and consumers as measured by changes in producer and consumer
surplus. For ease of exposition, the present discussion assumes that the producer absorbs the
entire cost of the regulation (i.e., no change in market prices or consumption occur), but the
main result can be generalized to cases where the burden is shared with consumers.

If producers absorb the full cost of a regulation, then their pre-tax profits decline by
the amount of the compliance cost. This is given by

An = -rK	(8.6)

However, producers pay taxes (T) to the government, based on their level of profits (II)

T = t»n	(8.7)

where t is the tax rate on profits. Because producer profits decline by the amount of the
compliance cost, their taxes fall as well. As a result the net post-tax loss to the producer is

APS = All • (1-t) =-rK • (1-t).	(8.8)

However, there is also the net loss in tax receipts to the government

AGS = -rK • t.	(8.9)

The total welfare loss due to the regulation, as measured in the market for the regulated
product, is

AWF = APS + AGS = -rK • t - rK • (1-t) = -rK.	(8.10)

8-20


-------
Section 8 — General Methodological Issues

Therefore, pre-tax measures, such as the market rate of return on capital, determine the
absolute size of welfare effects, though the distribution is affected by taxes. This
demonstrates the point that the private cost of capital is the appropriate measure for
estimating welfare impacts (annualized capital costs) in the regulated market.

General Conclusion about Discounting Costs in EIAs. An EIA can and should vary
the market assumptions to generate a case between the full-cost pass-through and absorption
extremes presented here, wherein the burden is shared between consumers and producers in
the affected markets (and taxpayers). The magnitude of these impacts, however distributed,
will still be determined by the producers' cost of capital. Thus, the prescription for capital
discounting seems clear for EIAs—use the pre-tax rate of return on capital to measure the
welfare impacts on the direct parties of interest. In fact, the EPA White Paper on discounting,
which recommends against the use of the pre-tax rate of return on capital for estimating the
social cost of a regulation under some circumstances, specifically recommends the use of this
rate in the estimation of private-sector economic impacts in all circumstances. The (potential)
difference between economic impacts and social costs is discussed in more detail below.

8.3.4.3 Reconciling Social Costs in an EIA with "True " Social Costs

In contrast to the sector-specific emphasis of the EIA, most of the theoretical literature
on the discount rate for SBCAs implicitly addresses the issue from a more aggregate
(economywide) perspective. In that context, the cost of a regulation is what society gives up
by mandated private expenditures on pollution control. The sectoral and economywide
perspectives are reconciled here and the extent to which they affect selection of the discount
rate and calculation of social costs is addressed.

Capital Market Factors. Following Lind (1990) the current literature suggests that
selection of the social discount rate depends on which of the following hypotheses about the
capital market holds:

•	The supply of capital to the economy is fixed ("closed economy").

•	The supply of capital to the economy is variable ("open economy").

Each is discussed in turn below.

Capital Costs Under the Closed Economy Hypothesis. Under the closed economy
hypothesis, mandated pollution control expenditures, by definition, displace other forms of
private investment. As a result, the social opportunity cost of the mandate is the pre-tax

8-21


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

private rate of return of capital (i.e., the value of market goods and services that could have
been generated had the displaced private investment occurred). More to the point of the
present discussion, if the fixed capital/closed economy assumption holds, then the estimate of
net welfare impacts from an EIA, which derives from the pre-tax rate of return of private
capital, is a valid measure of social costs.

Argument for Lower Capital Cost Under the Open Economy Hypothesis . The gist of
the open economy argument is capital supplied to any one industry is almost perfectly elastic;
therefore, virtually limitless capital can be supplied to that industry without affecting the world
price for capital. Moreover, the effect of environmental regulation's capital requirements on
the U.S. economy, much less any one industry, is small relative to the global supply of capital
and all other global capital demands. Thus, it is seen as unlikely that the global price of capital
will change in response to a particular environmental regulation. Because the capital price
does not change, the argument goes, all investments opportunities that would have been taken
in the absence of the regulation will still be taken (i.e., no capital is displaced as a result of the
regulation). For now, this is taken to mean that society does not forego investment
opportunities to fund pollution control; rather it foregoes consumption. The consistency of
the no-capital-displacement assertion with a model of global capital market equilibrium is
addressed in more detail below.

If one accepts the notion that a regulation's capital requirements replace consumption
rather than investment, the crucial point is that the opportunity costs of consumption and
investment generally differ because of tax distortions in the U.S. and most other market
economies. As discussed above, the opportunity cost of consumption is generally lower than
the opportunity cost of capital. This point is demonstrated by reference to a model of a
perfectly functioning, undistorted capital market. In such a world, the market rate of interest
would simultaneously equal both the consumption rate of time preference and the private rate
of return of capital. Any distinction about which discount rate to use would be moot—the
market interest rate would serve the purpose. However, capital markets in most market
economies, including the U.S., have a systematic distortion stemming from the fact that capital
income is taxed and consumption (for all intents and purposes) is not. Therefore, capital
investments must generate a pre-tax rate of return that is sufficient to satisfy the investor's
willingness to trade consumption, which is purchased with post-tax income, between time
periods. Therefore, in equilibrium, the capital market should produce the following
relationship:

8-22


-------
Section 8 — General Methodological Issues

r( 1 —trK) = p.	(8.11)

The consumption rate of interest (p) equals the after-tax rate of return on private capital
investment (r), which is presented as taxed at the rate, trK.7 In short, the price at which
individuals trade consumption through time (p) is lower than the rate at which capital
generates consumable goods and services (r). Thus if pollution control expenditures replace
consumption, the social costs are lower than if they replace capital investment.

The gap between the consumption rate of interest and the rate of return of capital has
long been recognized and has been the impetus for the shadow price of capital (SPC)
approach for discounting costs (Bradford, 1975). The SPC view is operationalized into the
two-stage discounting procedure described above. Because it is a common practice in EIAs
and SBCAs to express costs on an annualized basis, the critical point is that the pre-tax rate of
return of capital should be used to compute the annualized cost. Thus, the social cost process
outlined in the EIA discussion is entirely consistent with the SPC approach.

While the SPC view explicitly recognizes the difference between consumption and
investment opportunity costs, the two-stage method still follows the implicit assumption that
pollution control expenditures displace private capital investment. That is the premise of
stage 1, in which the capital allocated to pollution control is converted to its consumption
equivalent, that is, the amount of consumption (income) that could have been generated by a
private investment. However, the open economy adherents would reject the stage 1
adjustment, or at least make it so that the consumption rate of the interest, p, is used in the
stage 1 annualized cost assessment, thereby making the entire adjustment process redundant.
In other words, the open economy view holds that no investment is displaced by the
regulatory requirement; therefore, no upward adjustment for the opportunity cost of capital is
necessary.

As a practical matter, this suggests that the market adjustment made in the EIA model,
which is based on the private capital cost of r, leads to an overstatement of the true social
opportunity cost of the regulation if the open economy assumption holds. Under the limiting
case of capital with an infinite service life, the degree of overstatement is roughly given by the
ratio of the two discount rates, r/p. For instance, if the EIA impacts are computed using a
market rate of, say, 7 percent and the corresponding consumption rate of interest is 3 percent,

7Details on taxation of private capital investments and how that may differ between suppliers and demanders
of capital are presented below.

8-23


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

EIA social cost impacts would overstate true aggregate social cost impacts by a factor of
more than two. The distortion is reduced when finite capital service lives are considered.

Reconciling the Difference Between the Open Economy and Closed Economy
Measures. It has thus far been argued that the pre-tax rate of return of capital, r, should
generally be used for an EIA and that the consumption rate of interest, p, may be appropriate
for estimating aggregate social costs under some circumstances. Given that this approach will
lead to sectoral impacts that exceed social impacts, who in society receives the offsetting gains
that are ignored in a typical EIA?

As demonstrated above, when investable funds are assumed fixed, the losses to the
private sector and government (which sum up to the total social cost) equal the private cost of
capital. However, when capital is fully mobile through a global capital market, the argument
has been made that no investment has been displaced, only consumption. From the aggregate
welfare perspective, the funds needed for pollution control in Industry X are reallocated from
nontaxed activity (consumption) to a taxed activity (investment). Therefore, the government
receives an increase in tax revenue directly from the new investment activity in the amount of
(trK • rK). Drawing again from the full-cost absorption example, Eqs. (8.9) to (8.10) are
restated as follows:

APS =-rK • (1-t)	(8.12)

AGS = -rK • t + rK • trK = -rK(t-trK).	(8.13)

If the tax rate on profits is the same as the tax rate on investment income (t = trK), then the
loss in profits tax due to the mandated investment is just offset by the gain in taxes from the
capital income. Thus, the net effect on government revenues would be zero. In that case, the
net welfare cost of the regulation is

AWF = APS = -rK • (1-t)	(8.14)

indicating that the after-tax rate of return of capital is the appropriate measure of social costs.
In an efficient capital market, the after-tax rate of return of capital equals the consumption
rate of interest (Eq. 8.9). Therefore, the consumption rate of interest would be used for
discounting costs in this case.

In essence, while taxpayers were shown to bear part of the burden through a loss in
profits tax under the closed economy/EIA model, they bear none of the burden in the open

8-24


-------
Section 8 — General Methodological Issues

economy model. So regarding the question of who gains in the aggregate social cost
computation versus the sectoral impacts computation of social cost? The taxpayer.

More on Global Capital Markets and the Implications for Social Cost. The open
economy arguments put forward by Lind (1990) and the EPA white papers on discounting
(Arnold, Sussman, and Deck 1997) rely largely on heuristic descriptions of the global capital
market and international flows of funds. To illuminate the displacement issue further, a simple
model of a global capital market is put forth here.

The global supply of capital is a function of the global price of capital (r):

SG=SG(r).	(8.15)

The global demand for capital is the sum of the demand from U.S. Industry X that is directly
affected by the regulation (Dx), all other U.S. industries (D, ), and all other sources of
investment demand in the rest of the world (Dw):

Dg = Dx(r) + Du(r) + Dw(r).	(8.16)

The global capital market equilibrium equates global supply with global demand:

SG = DG = Dx(r) + Du(r) + Dw(r).	(8.17)

The equilibrium supply of capital to Industry X (Sx) is the "excess supply" of global capital
not demanded by all other sources in the world market:

Sx = SG(r)-Du(r)-Dw(r).	(8.18)

Therefore, if the regulation imposes capital requirements that cause Industry X to increase its
demand for investable funds, those funds must be supplied by some combination of an increase
in global capital supply, displacement of capital invested in Industry X, displacement of capital
to other U.S. industries, or displacement of capital to the rest of the world.

The common interpretation of the open economy hypothesis is that no investment is
displaced by the claims on the capital market placed by regulatory capital requirements. Yet
the global capital market equilibrium just described suggests that the capital needed for the
expenditure mandated by the regulation must be diverted either from consumption or other
capital uses to maintain a global equilibrium. But if the capital price does not change at all,
there is no mechanism by which capital supplies will increase or capital will be diverted from
other capital uses to fund the regulated industry's capital requirements.

8-25


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Perhaps a more correct interpretation of the implications of a global capital market can
be stated as follows. The investment requirements for a typical industry-level regulation are so
small relative to world capital markets that

•	the effect on the global capital price is indetectable and

•	the displacement of global consumption, U.S. investment, and non-U.S. investment
is imperceptibly small, relative to baseline values.

Thus, the notion that the global markets are essentially unaffected by the regulation's capital
requirements would not be far from the truth.8 In other words, a regulation requiring $20
million worth of capital expenditures is, no doubt, too small to materially alter the world
capital rate or to have a noticeable effect on net global investment. However, it seems quite a
different matter to conclude that the $20 million did not involve the displacement of other
capital. Re-establishment of a global capital market equilibrium suggests that the $20 million
must be supplied to Industry X through some combination of displaced consumption and
displaced capital in other uses. Thus, the opportunity costs of the capital allocated to Industry
X's compliance requirements will be a weighted average of the opportunity costs of displaced
consumption and investment.

The extent to which displaced global consumption and displaced non-U.S.
investment—rather than displaced U.S. investment—supplies the capital for Industry X's
regulatory compliance will bring the (U.S.) social opportunity cost closer to the lower-bound
(consumption rate) value proposed above. Again, this is because the regulation causes the
substitution of taxed activity (U.S. investment) for nontaxed activity (consumption and non-
U.S. investment). This reduces the burden borne by U.S. taxpayers in terms of reduced profit
taxes from Industry X. Of course, the extent to which it is consumption and non-U.S.
investment that is displaced, rather than U.S. investment, is an empirical issue.

8.3.4.4 Practical Concerns for the Policymaker and Analyst

The implications of the open economy model and the subsequent reduction in the
social cost estimate raise a number of questions that are potentially crucial to the policy
assessment. Two particularly important points are raised here.

8This is not inconsistent with the views attributed to Blinder (1985) and stated in Lind (1990, p. S-15) that
crowding out (in their case due to deficit financing) is more likely to be small, rather than nonexistent
when viewed in the context of global capital markets.

8-26


-------
Section 8 — General Methodological Issues

• Is it reasonable to assume that pollution control will not affect other investment
opportunities for the regulated industry?

Whether private investment is displaced by pollution control seems, at least, an
empirical question worthy of further pursuit, rather than a foregone conclusion by
those advocating either the higher or lower discount rate. Macroeconomic studies
of the relationship between government deficits and investment suggest that
government deficits do not crowd out private investment (e.g., Evans, 1985).

These findings have supported the notion that open global capital markets work to
prevent federal deficits from crowding out investment and raising interest rates.
The Lind (1990) article thus implies that the crowding out effect is not a terribly
important consideration in the selection of a social discount rate for public
expenditures. This has sparked the drawing of similar conclusions for the analysis
of pollution control requirements and support for the use of the consumption-
based discount rate (i), as described above. However, empirical studies that have
looked specifically at mandated pollution control expenditures typically find a
relationship between pollution control and other investment. Viscusi (1983) shows
that environmental regulation can reduce productive investment due to the
uncertainty it implies for investment returns. Gray and Shadbegian's (1997) study
of environmental regulation in the pulp and paper industry finds that pollution
control expenditures almost fully crowd out "productive" investment.

The degree of friction in the regulated industry's access to capital markets will
largely determine whether investment crowding takes place. If access to credit
markets is constrained for pollution control investments, there is a stronger case
that other private investments would be displaced and the opportunity cost would
be captured by r, rather than i. These issues may be worth further scrutiny in an
EIA if the regulated industry is dominated by small companies with limited debt
capacity.

To summarize the point, the potential for fully mobile global capital to mitigate the
social costs of public programs is an important theoretical development in the
economics literature. However, the application of this principle to the particular
environmental regulation being analyzed should be justified empirically.

8-27


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

• Even when private investment is not displaced, is it reasonable to assume that
tax revenues will be unaffected by pollution control investment?

The exact canceling out of tax effects as implied by Eq. (8.13) is unlikely to occur
in practice. First, the corporate tax rate (t) will generally differ from the tax rate
on investment income (fK) for U.S. citizens, which itself may differ from the tax
rate on foreign investment income.9 Second, the tax effects on regulated
producers will be affected by rules governing cost recovery of depreciable assets.
Third, there are state taxes to consider. Finally, the tax outcome is further
complicated by the extent to which the funds used for pollution control capital are
provided through debt, equity, or retained earnings. While it is possible to address
some of these tax complications in an EIA, resource limitations will likely make it
impractical to quantify the effect of these factors on the selection of a discount
rate.

8.3.5 Empirical Evidence on Discount Rates

At this point, the reader may be misled to the conclusion that once one resolves the
conceptual issues surrounding which discount rate to use (consumption rate or return to
capital), the entire discounting problem has been solved. Unfortunately this is not the case,
because complex capital markets generate a wide range of market rates that vary by factors
such as the time commitment of funds and the degree of risk of the investment. As a result,
there is no clear consensus about the appropriate rate to use either for the consumption rate of
interest or the rate of return of capital. Some empirical evidence is presented below.

8.3.5.1 Consumption Rate of Interest

Market rates of return on relatively risk-free lending (e.g., Treasury bills) are often
viewed as the appropriate proxy for the consumption rate of interest. Lind (1990), Moore and
Viscusi (1990), and Freeman (1993) all argue for real (inflation-adjusted) rates in the 1 to

'Personal and corporate tax rates are probably more similar in the mid-1990s than they have been historically.
Corporate tax rates in 1997 ranged from 15 to 38 percent (IRS Form 1120 instructions), while personal tax
rates ranged from 15 to 39.6 percent (IRS Form 1040 instructions). However the highest personal income
tax rates apply only to very high income households ($271,050 in taxable income). The amount of tax
withheld from investment income accruing to foreign entities depends on the status of income tax treaties
(or conventions) between the U.S. and the foreign country of interest. Foreign residents (sometimes
limited to citizens) of those countries are often taxed at a reduced rate or are exempt from U.S. income
taxes on certain income received from within the U.S. (IRS, 1998).

8-28


-------
Section 8 — General Methodological Issues

4 percent range for the consumption rate of interest. Lipscomb, Weinstein, and Torrance
(1996) recommend a rate of 3 percent as the most reflective of real riskless rates of return.
There is precedence elsewhere in EPA for using a 3 percent rate as representative of the
consumption rate of interest (EPA, 1996).

8.3.5.2 Rate of Return on Private Capital

The 7 percent rate recommended by OMB (1992) is the point of departure for any
discussion of private cost of capital in regulatory analysis. This rate is supposed to reflect the
marginal pre-tax rate of return on an average private-sector investment. The OMB circular
also stipulates that "analyses should show the sensitivity of the discounted net present value
and other outcomes to variations in the discount rate. The importance of these alternative
calculations will depend on the specific economic characteristics of the program under
analysis" [Section 8(b)(2)], Therefore, there seems to be some leeway to modify the analysis
to reflect industry-specific real rates of return that are lower or higher than percent as part of a
sensitivity analysis. For an EIA, knowledge of industry- (and firm-) specific capital cost
factors will provide a more accurate analysis of distributional effects. Moreover, if the flow of
capital funds is limited to the point that pollution control is thought to displace other forms of
investment within the regulated sector (i.e., the "closed economy" assumption holds), then
these foregone rates of return represent the magnitude of the social cost. Industry-specific
rates of return on capital can be obtained from secondary data sources, such as Dun &
Bradstreet.

8.3.6 Discounting Recommendations

The first, and strongest, recommendation is to use the pre-tax rate of return on private
capital investment to discount costs for the typical EIA. "Typical" means an EIA for a
regulation that mandates control responsibilities for a specific industry.10 The rationale for this
is that the private cost of capital determines the magnitude of these control cost
responsibilities and therefore the size of the burden that will be determined by the sum of
changes in producer and consumer surplus within the regulated sector, the focal point of an
EIA. The OMB-recommended discount rate (7 percent) is the suggested default value for the
real private cost of capital. If warranted, industry- and firm-specific rates of return can be
used to modify this rate via sensitivity analysis. Also, to the extent that an EIA addresses

10Refer to Section 5 for a description of the typical industry-level analysis that is the focus of this document.

8-29


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

compliance requirements for the public sector, government borrowing costs should be
considered, rather than the private rates.

A case has been stated that pollution control requirements in general may not displace
other private investment in the U.S. economy. If so, then the sector-specific social cost
estimate from the EIA, which uses the pre-tax rate of return of capital, must be transformed to
a (lower) social cost value for SBCA, one based on the consumption rate of interest.

Table 8-1 provides an example for the simplifying case of a regulation whose costs are entirely
capital expenditures with an infinite service (i.e., expenditures are annualized into perpetuity).

Table 8-1. Transformation of Social Costs from an EIA to BCA



Required Capital

Discount

Annual

Type of Analysis

Expenditures

Rate

Equivalent Cost

Economic Impact Analysis

$500 MM

7%

$35 MM

Benefit-Cost Analysis

$500 MM

3%

$15 MM

The cost estimate is reduced by more than 50 percent.11 However, before making this
transformation, the analyst should examine the empirical justification for doing so. Most
importantly, does the evidence support the case that investment will not be displaced for the
regulation in question? This may depend on characteristics of the industry and on the nature
of the control responsibilities themselves. It is unlikely that a clear answer will result from
this inquiry, so the analyst's most prudent strategy may be to present benefit-cost results both
with and without the social cost transformation outlined above. This allows the analyst to
determine whether the transformation has a decisive impact on the benefit-cost results and if
the issue warrants further scrutiny.

8.4 Addressing Uncertainty

Because they are estimates, the results of an economic analysis of a regulatory action
are never precise; however, many EAs present simple point estimates of expected benefits and
costs without characterizing the uncertainties surrounding these values. Both EPA and OMB

"The magnitude of the cost difference is amplified by the infinite life assumption. If the capital equipment has
a useful life of, for example, 15 years, then the annualized cost at 3 percent is only about one-quarter less
than the annualized cost at 7 percent.

8-30


-------
Section 8 — General Methodological Issues

guidance require that such uncertainties be acknowledged and addressed in an EA. Therefore,
the purpose of this section is to identify sources of uncertainty in EAs and to discuss methods
available to analysts for characterizing and reducing uncertainty in the results of the analysis.

The term "uncertainty" simply refers to the confidence with which any estimate can be
accepted as representing the true result of a process about which the analyst has incomplete
knowledge.12 It is important to note that in this discussion "uncertainty" is not used as a
synonym for risk. The term "risk" is interpreted to mean the likelihood of a particular event
occurring. For example, some OAQPS regulations are expected to result in a change in the
probability that an individual or ecosystem will experience an effect as a result of an exposure
to air pollution.13 The level of this change in risk is a truth unknown to the analyst and is
independent of the techniques used to estimate the risk. In contrast, uncertainty in the
assessment of risk is an artifact of the analysis itself and can often be reduced by further study.

Uncertainty can arise at any stage in the development of a regulatory analysis. Within
each stage of the analysis, uncertainty can result from any number of factors, including
insufficient data, an incomplete understanding of the physical or economic process being
modeled, model specification, and the inherent uncertainty in the results of any statistical
analysis. A thorough treatment of all sources of uncertainty in a regulatory analysis is beyond
the scope of this document. Therefore, the remainder of this discussion focuses on the
uncertainties associated with the valuation of changes in environmental impacts.

There are three general sources of uncertainty in the economic analysis of a regulatory
action: input uncertainty, model uncertainty, and estimation uncertainty. Each of these
sources of uncertainty is described below:

• Input uncertainty—This is a general term used to describe two specific sources of
uncertainty inherent in the data on which an economic analysis is based. These
specific sources include the distribution of possible values of the environmental

12Both the OMB EA guidance (OMB, 1996) and the EPA working paper addressing uncertainty in EAs
(Hagler-Bailly Consulting, Inc., 1997) include a discussion of certainty equivalents. Certainty equivalents
are a theoretical construct for the value that a risk-averse individual places on an uncertain outcome. This
type of uncertainty does not represent a lack of knowledge on the part of the analyst but rather a component
of an individual's response to risk. Therefore, certainty equivalents are more appropriately addressed in a
discussion of the expected benefits of a regulatory action rather than in a discussion of analytical
uncertainty.

13Risk and risk assessment are discussed in detail in Section 7 of this guidance document.

8-31


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

impact being valued and measurement error. The former source of input
uncertainty arises when the impacts being valued are themselves the product of a
modeling effort as is often the case when the impact of interest is a change in
exposure to a pollutant or a change in the probability of a certain outcome
occurring. The latter source of input uncertainty, measurement error, is common
when the data used in an economic analysis are incomplete and analyst judgement
or proxy measures are used to fill in data gaps. The uncertainty surrounding such
inputs will naturally be carried through the economic analysis.

•	Model uncertainty—This type of uncertainty is typically a result of the fact that
any statistical model represents a simplification of a behavioral or economic
process. This simplification is often necessary because most behavioral and
economic processes are highly complex. In addition, this simplification is
necessary if the nature of the behavioral or economic process being modeled is not
completely understood. In modeling such processes, analysts must often rely on a
series of assumptions and abstractions, each having a potential impact on the
precision of the analytical results.

•	Estimation uncertainty—Economic analyses in which the analyst estimates a
parametric model yield results that are variable. In particular, all statistical
modeling techniques result in parameter estimates that are not point estimates, but
rather probability distributions of likely values for the parameters. This distribution
in parameter estimates naturally translates into a distribution of the predicted
outcome variable. This estimation uncertainty requires that the analyst take care
to assign the appropriate probability ranges around each estimated parameter or
prediction.

Because of the uncertainties described above, the results of an EA must be presented
in such a way that the full range of uncertainty is transparent. There are five basic methods
for characterizing uncertainty:

•	scenario analysis—estimating a range of possible outcomes, such as worst-case
and best-case scenarios, in addition to the most likely outcome

•	Delphi methods—using input from a group of experts to characterize the potential
likelihood of possible outcomes

•	sensitivity analysis—identifying assumptions made about key input variables (e.g.,
the level of exposure or the discount rate) and conducting the analysis over a range
of plausible values for these variables to determine the effect of each assumption
on the resulting point estimates

8-32


-------
Section 8 — General Methodological Issues

•	meta-analysis—combining data or results from a number of different studies to
estimate a more general model or to characterize the range or distribution of key
input variables

•	Monte Carlo and other probabilistic methods—simulating a distribution of the
results by randomly drawing from the probability distributions of input variables
and repeating the analysis numerous times

The draft EPA white paper on uncertainty recommends that, at a minimum, the analyst
identify the key assumptions and qualitatively assess the potential impact of each assumption
on the results of the analysis (Hagler-Bailly Consulting, Inc., 1997).

In addition, sensitivity analysis should be conducted to further characterize the impact
of alternative values of key variables whenever possible. Scenario analysis and Delphi
methods are useful when sensitivity analysis fails to adequately characterize the range of
possible outcomes, particularly in situations in which there is a small risk of an extreme
outcome. Meta-analysis and probabilistic methods are often superior to the other methods.
Meta-analysis provides a more complete characterization of key input variables, and
probabilistic methods provide a probability distribution for the full range of possible cost and
benefit values.

Because Delphi methods, meta-analysis,14 and probabilistic methods15 often require
substantial time and financial resources, the analyst should determine their likely contribution
to the policy implications of the EA results. For analyses in which benefits unambiguously
exceed costs, a sensitivity analysis should be adequate. However, in cases in which the results
vary significantly depending on the underlying assumptions, other methods of characterizing
the range and distribution of both input variables and results should be considered.

14For an example of the use of meta-analysis in determining the value of a statistical life to use in the analysis
of environmental programs, readers are referred to EPA's analysis of the benefits and costs of the CAA
(EPA, 1996a). Analysts interested in conducting meta-analyses are referred to Hedges and Olkin (1985)
and Cook et al. (1992).

15An example of the use of Monte Carlo simulation in the analysis of a regulation is the CAA retrospective
analysis (EPA, 1996a). More detailed discussions of probabilistic methods, including Monte Carlo
simulations, can be found in most intermediate or advanced statistics and econometrics texts.

8-33


-------
Section 9 — Communicating the Results of the Economic Analysis

SECTION 9

COMMUNICATING Till RESULTS OF THE ECONOMIC ANALYSIS

The ultimate purpose for conducting the economic analyses described in this document
is to inform decisionmakers of the social welfare consequences of the regulatory actions under
OAQPS's consideration. One responsibility of the ISEG analyst is to develop a sound,
comprehensive analysis that addresses these concerns. Toward that end, sound analytical
methodology has been the primary focus of the document up to this point. However, another
equally important responsibility is to communicate the results of the analyses in a manner that
effectively influences decisionmaking. Without proper communication, the most well-
conducted analysis will fail to guide decisions. Therefore, communicating the results of
economic analysis to decisionmakers frequently, in a complete and understandable form, is an
important part of the development of well-reasoned environmental policy.

The purpose of this section is to provide some general guidance and specific tips for
communicating the results of economic analysis throughout the regulatory process. The
primary focus is not the EA or EIA document itself—that is addressed throughout the other
sections, especially in Section 4. Rather, this section focuses on the various opportunities that
ISEG analysts have to bring the economic analysis to bear in making decisions throughout the
regulatory process. A comprehensive treatment of communication issues is beyond the scope
of this chapter. For more on this topic, the reader may wish to refer to the following sources:

Written Communication

Barzun, Jacque. 1976. Simple and Direct: A Rhetoric for Writers. Harper and Row.

Zinsser, William. 1985. On Writing Well. Harper and Row. Third Edition.

Strunk, William, and E.B. White. The Elements of Style. MacMillan. Various editions.
The Chicago Manual of Style. University of Chicago Press. Various editions.

9-1


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Visual Communication

Booth, Wayne C., Gregory G. Colomb, and Joseph M. Williams. 1995. The Craft of

Research. University of Chicago Press. (See especially Chapter 12: Communicating
Evidence Visually).

Tufte, Edward R. 1997. Visual Explanations. Cheshire, CT: Graphics Press.

Tufte, Edward R. 1983. The Visual Display of Quantitative Information. Cheshire, CT:
Graphics Press.

Oral Communication

Beebe, Steven A., and Susan J. Beebe. 1997. Public Speaking: An Audience-Centered
Approach. Prentice-Hall.

Krannich, Caryl Rae. 1998. 101 Secrets of Highly Effective Speakers. Impact Publications.

9.1 Communication Goals, the Audience, and Challenges

It is important to keep in mind that ISEG performs economic analysis not only to
satisfy the various statutes and EOs by which the Agency is required to analyze the effects of
its regulations, but also to ensure that decisionmakers (both within and outside the Agency)
understand the full range of effects that Agency action (or inaction) will have on society.

Thus, any strategy for communicating analytical results should hold improved decisionmaking
as a central goal.

The opportunities ISEG analysts have to communicate analytical results throughout
the regulatory process range from workgroup meetings to stakeholder interactions to formal
presentations for senior Agency management. These exchanges may involve delivering
written summaries of the EA/EIA results (preliminary, proposed, final) and making oral
presentations. With either written or oral communication, it is important to target the
audience in determining both the content and the method of delivery. Different objectives
guide presentations to senior management, workgroup members, and stakeholders, so written
and oral communications to those groups should differ as well.

The analyst must determine the information that the audience needs to know, either to
make their decision (in the case of workgroup members or senior management) or to
understand the impact of the regulation on their particular constituency (in the case of

9-2


-------
Section 9 — Communicating the Results of the Economic Analysis

stakeholders). If the audience is overwhelmed with needless detail, they may miss an
important point.

ISEG analysts must consider the extent of the audience's background in economics. If
the audience is not familiar with economics principles and methods, the ISEG analyst must
present the analysis in a manner that is clear to a noneconomist. The audience should be able
to deduce the logic of the underlying analysis without relying on terms and concepts outside
their area of expertise. In this situation, the analyst should avoid excessive use of jargon.

Also, the analyst should consider what elements of economics noneconomists often find either
difficult to understand or, sometimes, difficult to accept: these include the concepts of
opportunity cost, values of statistical lives saved, and discounting future benefits and costs,
among others.

The basic principles of effective communication should be a guiding force, regardless
of the medium in which the information is being exchanged. The next section identifies key
principles relevant to communicating economics results.

9.2 Key Principles of Clear and Effective Communication1

To help the analyst present the results of economic analysis, six principles of
communication are identified and briefly described below.

• Use Clear and Transparent Language: As indicated above, the ultimate
objective of ISEG's economic analyses is to provide information to
decisionmakers. Therefore, all aspects of the analysis should be presented in such
a manner that the decisionmaker can completely understand the results of the
analysis and the methods by which the results were derived. Analytical results
should be able to withstand close scrutiny by the decisionmakers themselves and by
external parties. Making the analytical results clear helps achieve that goal. On
June 1, 1998, President Clinton issued a memorandum directing Federal executive
departments and agencies to use "plain language" in the development of all Federal
rulemaking activities. While the directive applies specifically to the publication of
FR notices (see Chapter 3), the spirit of the memorandum is to encourage clear,
understandable writing wherever possible.

'This discussion of communication principles borrows heavily from the draft guidance document Guidelines
for Preparing Economic Analyses, prepared by EPA's Office of Policy. As of this writing, a preliminary
draft of this document (July 1998d) is being circulated throughout the Agency for review and comment.

9-3


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

•	Identify Data Sources and Assumptions: The EA/EIA document should always
include a description of all data sources and references used in the analysis, subject
to confidentiality constraints imposed by CBI agreements. This information should
be presented in such a way that decisionmakers and other analysts can obtain these
data and other source materials with relative ease. In addition, the analyst should
clearly identify all relevant assumptions made in the course of the analysis.

•	Describe the Modeling: For those not trained in economics and other
quantitative disciplines, econometric and other economic models can often appear
unapproachable. Therefore, it is important that the analyst describe the modeling
techniques used in the analysis in clear and understandable terms. The level of
detail of such a discussion will depend on the technical expertise of the audience.
Analytical detail may be appropriate for an audience of economists but not for the
wide range of disciplines typically represented in the workgroup or senior
management. The discussion needs to be targeted to the audience. Providing the
basic reasoning underlying the modeling framework not only bolsters the
credibility of the results among noneconomists, but it also ensures that
decisionmakers correctly interpret the results of the model.

•	Characterize Uncertainty: As discussed at length in Section 7 of this manual, all
EAs are subject to uncertainty. Uncertainty may arise from data, models, or
general lack of information. When summarizing results for decisionmakers, the
analyst should identify uncertainties that could alter a decision and explain the
implications of plausible alternative assumptions.

•	Make Alternatives Comparable: Because several regulatory alternatives are
often evaluated at different stages in the regulatory process, the process of
narrowing the field to a preferred alternative requires some form of direct
comparison. The ideal way to communicate the full range of consequences of a
regulatory option is to convert all of these consequences to a single metric. From
the perspective of welfare economics, the most sensible metric is monetary,
because it provides a platform for comparing the benefits of the action with its
costs (i.e., the benefits that society foregoes to obtain the benefits of the
regulation) in a manner that is consistent with the tradeoffs that members of
society make all the time—the exchange of dollars for goods and services.

•	Clearly Identify Nonmonetized and Nonqualified Effects: Often some of the
consequences of a regulatory action are not able to be quantified or monetized. To
the extent that the regulatory action being analyzed is expected to result in such
costs or benefits, monetized benefits and costs may misrepresent the full range of
impacts of the regulation. Therefore, it is important to clearly present the full
range of benefits and costs that cannot be quantified or monetized. One way to

9-4


-------
Section 9 — Communicating the Results of the Economic Analysis

present these is through a table structured similarly to Table 9-1. Potential health
effects of the regulatory action are identified, a subset of those identified are
shown to be quantified in the analysis, and a subset of those quantified are shown
to be monetized. This presentation provides some sense of the extent and nature
of the omissions from the monetary estimate of benefits. This may become critical
information if the monetized costs exceed the monetized benefits, in which case the
decisionmakers must evaluate whether the implicit value of the nonmonetized
benefits is high enough to favor regulatory action.

The method of presentation is particularly important for two types of economic

results:

•	net social benefits, and

•	equity effects and economic impacts.

Table 9-2 provides an example of how net benefits results can be presented in an
understandable manner. Eight different regulatory options are evaluated, starting with the
least stringent option at the top of the table and working down to the most stringent

Table 9-1. Identified, Quantified, and Monetized Health Effects

Identified Health Effect

Quantified	Monetized

Children Health Effects

Neonatal mortality
Fetal developmental effects
Reduced intelligence
Growth interference

~

~

~

~

Adult Health Effects
Premature death

~

~

Hypertension
Nonfatal heart attack

~

~

~

Reproductive effects

9-5


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Table 9-2. Sample Table of Net Benefits Estimates—Annual Net Benefits of Regulatory
Options3



Option

Annual Benefitsb'c
($ million)

Annual Costs
($ million)

Total Net Benefits
Per Year
($ million)

1.

Performance Standard A

10

7

3

2.

Performance Standard B

33

12

21

3.

Performance Standard C

40

20

20

4.

Performance Standard D

50

38

12

5.

Incentive Option A

75

35

40

6.

Incentive Option B

85

50

35

7.

Incentive Option C

100

75

25

8.

Incentive Option D

120

115

5

a Options are listed in order of increasing total benefits.

b The following effects on children could not be quantified and are not included in the benefits estimates:
interference with growth, interference with nervous system development, impaired hearing, behavioral
changes, metabolic effects, impaired heme synthesis, and anemia.
c Blood-pressure related effects could not be quantified for adult women and for selected age groupings of
adult men and are therefore not included in the above benefits estimates. Similarly, reproductive effects in
women could not be quantified.

option. Monetized benefits and costs are presented in separate columns. This presentation
allows the reader to trace results presented in the table back to the respective cost or benefits
chapter or section. The far right column presents the results (monetized net benefits). It is
transparent to the reader that the net benefits estimate equals benefits less costs. For external
comparisons, the table could include the year in which the dollars are denominated. If there
are significant nonquantified or nonmonetized benefits or costs to consider, another column
might be added to the right of the monetized net benefits column to identify these factors.

As discussed throughout this document, the focus of equity/impacts analysis is on the
distributional consequences of rulemakings. The general analytical requirements for these
analyses are outlined in Section 6. The key point in terms of presenting the results of these

9-6


-------
Section 9 — Communicating the Results of the Economic Analysis

analyses is to ensure that the results are sufficiently disaggregated to show impacts separately
for the groups and sectors of interest.

9.3 A Note on Visual Communication

When the audience represents a diverse group of backgrounds and disciplines and
particularly when the venue for communication is constrained by space or time, visual
communication (graphs, charts, illustrations) often helps make the key points to the reader or
audience. Supplementary to the age-old counsel that "a picture is worth a thousand words" is
a telling passage found in one of the communications texts referenced at the beginning of this
section:

If displays of data are to be truthful and revealing, then the logic
of the display design must reflect the logic of the analysis ...

Clear and precise seeing becomes as one with clear and precise
thinking. (Tufte, 1997, p. 53)

Following this advice will help strengthen the link between sound analysis on the one hand and
sound regulatory decisionmaking or a clear understanding of stakeholder impacts on the other.
Not only should visual communication reflect the logic of the analysis, but the need to display
results visually can also lead to a more logical analytic design.

Again, the reader can turn to the texts referenced at the beginning of the chapter for a
more thorough treatment of the use of visual aids in reports and presentations. An example
here can elucidate some key points. Tables such as Table 9-2 are ideal for reports, when the
reader can take some time to inspect the detail. However, in an oral presentation, the
audience might be distracted in their attempt to interpret the tabular data. Charts can provide
a solution to this problem. Figure 9-1 translates the net benefits data from Table 9-2 to bar
charts, where the apparent dominance of Incentive Option A and Incentive Option B becomes
immediately apparent. Of course, information is lost in the translation—in this case, the
underlying levels of benefits and costs. In each case, the presenter should evaluate whether
the benefits of the simpler graphic approach (ease and speed of interpretation) outweigh the
costs (lost information) in terms of meeting the information needs of the audience.

9-7


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

u

a

CU ^

sS	°


-------
References

REFERENCES

Abt Associates. 1992. Regulatory Impact Analysis of Control Options for Urea-
Formaldehyde Pressed Wood.

Adams, James D. 1985. "Permanent Differences in Unemployment and Permanent Wage
Differentials." Quarterly Journal of Econometrics 100(l):29-56.

American Business Information, Inc. (ABI). 1997. American Business Disk, [computer file]
Omaha, NE: American Business Information.

Anderson, D.W., and Ram V. Chandran. 1987. "Market Estimates of Worker Dislocation
Costs." Economic Letters 24:381-384.

Arnold, Frank S., Frances G. Sussman, and Leland B. Deck. 1997. "Discounting in
Environmental Policy Evaluation." Draft final report.

Arnold, Frank S. 1995. Economic Analysis of Environmental Policy and Regulation. New
York: John Wiley & Sons.

Arora, S. and T.N. Cason. 1996. "Why Do Firms Volunteer to Exceed Environmental
Regulations? Understanding Participation in EPA's 33/50 Program." Land
Economics 72(4):413-32.

Ayers, R., and J. Walter. 1991. The Greenhouse Effect: Damages, Costs and Abatement."
Environmental and Resource Economics 1:237-270.

Bernabo, J. C., K. D. Smythe, N. S. Baer, and F. W. Lipfert. 1988. Materials Degradation
and Acidic Deposition. Palo Alto, CA: Electric Power Research Institute.

Berndt, Ernst R. 1991. The Practice of Econometrics: Classic and Contemporary.

Reading: Addison-Wesley.

Brewer, R.F., and R. Ashcroft. 1982. "The Effects of Ozone and S02 on Alfalfa Yields and
Hay Quality." Prepared for the California Air Resources Board. #Al-038-33.

R-l


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Browner, Carol M. Memorandum on Initiation of EPA's Regulatory and Policy Development
Process. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Office of the Administrator. July 1,
1994.

Byerly, Edwin R., and Kevin Deardorff. 1995. National and State Population Estimates:
1990 to 1994. U.S. Bureau of the Census, Current Population Reports, P25-1127.
Washington, DC: 1995. U.S. Government Printing Office.

Campbell, Paul R. 1997. Population Projections for States by Age, Sex, Race and Hispanic
Origin: 1995 to 2025. PPL-47. U.S. Bureau of the Census, Population Division.

Chambers, Robert G. 1988. Applied Production Analysis: A Dual Approach. New York:
Cambridge University Press.

Chestnut, L.G., D. Mills, and A. Alberini. July 1997. "Monetary Valuation of Human

Mortality Risks in Cost-Benefits Analyses of Environmental Programs: Background
Paper and Bibliography." Prepared for U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Office
of Policy, Planning, and Evaluation.

Clarke, B.B., M.R. Henninger, and E. Brennan. 1983. "An Assessment of Potato Losses
Caused by Oxidant Air Pollution in New Jersey." Phytopathology 73:104-108.

Companies Online, [on-line] .

Company Web Sites. .

Cook, Thomas D., Harris Cooper, David S. Cordray, Heidi Hartman, Larry V. Hedges,

Richard J. Light, Thomas A. Louis, and Frederick Mosteller. 1992. Meta-Analysis
for Explanation. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

Day, Jennifer Cheeseman. 1996. Population Projections of the United States by Age, Sex,
Race, and Hispanic Origin: 1995 to 2050. U.S. Bureau of the Census, Current
Population Reports, P25-1130. Washington, DC. U.S. Government Printing Office.

Dickie, M., and S. Gerking. 1991. "Valuing Reduced Morbidity: A Household Production
Approach." Southern Economic Journal 57(3):690-702.

Directory of Corporate Affiliations. 1997. New Providence, RI: National Register
Publishing.

R-2


-------
References

Dixit, Avinash K., and Robert S. Pindyck. 1994. Investment Under Uncertainty. Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press.

Dun & Bradstreet. 1997a. D & B Million Dollar Directory: America's Leading Public and
Private Companies. Bethlehem, PA: Dun & Bradstreet Corporation.

Dun & Bradstreet. 1997b. Industry Norms & Key Business Ratios. Murray Hill, NJ: Dun &
Bradstreet Corporation.

Fankhauser, S., and D.W. Pearce. 1994. "The Social Costs of Greenhouse Gas Emissions."
The Economics of Climate Change. Proceedings of an OECD/IEA Conference, Paris.
P. 71-86.

Fankhauser, Samuel. 1994. "The Social Costs of Greenhouse Gas Emissions: An Expected
Value Approach." The Energy Journal 15(2): 157-184.

Flaim, Paul O. 1984. "Unemployment in 1982: The Cost to Workers and Their Families."
Monthly Labor Review Feb:30-37.

Foster, K.W., H. Timm, D.K. Labanauskas, and R.J. Oshima. 1983. "Effects of Ozone and
Sulfur Dioxide on Tuber Yield and Quality of Potatoes." Journal of Environmental
Quality 12(l):75-80.

Friedman, Milton. 1962. Price Theory: A Provisional Text. Chicago: Aldine Publishing
Company.

Freeman, A. Myrick, III. 1993. The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values:
Theory and Methods. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.

Gale Research Company. Annual. Manufacturing U.S.A. Detroit, MI: Gale Research
Incorporated.

Gale Research Company. Serial. Encyclopedia of Associations. Detroit, MI: Gale Research
Incorporated.

Gale Research Company. 1994. Encyclopedia of American Industries. Detroit, MI: Gale
Research Incorporated.

Gale Research Company. 1995. U.S. Industry Profiles: The Leading 100. Detroit, MI:

Gale Research Incorporated.

R-3


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Gale Research. 1997a. Ward's Business Directory: Manufacturing USA: 1998. Detroit,
MI: Gale Research, Incorporated.

Gale Research. 1997b. Ward's Business Directory of U.S. Private and Public Companies:
1998. Detroit, MI: Gale Research, Incorporated.

Gale Research Company. 1998. How Products Are Made. Detroit, MI: Gale Research
Incorporated.

Hagler-Bailly Consulting, Inc. 1997. Technical Assistance on a Review and Evaluation of
Procedures Used to Study Issues of Uncertainty in the Conduct of Economic Cost-
Benefit Research and Analysis. Prepared for the U.S. Environmental Protection
Agency.

Hamermesh, Daniel S. 1989. "What Do We Know About Worker Displacement in the
U.S.?" Industrial Relations 28(1):51-59.

Harberger, Arnold C. 1974. Taxation and Welfare. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Hazilla, Michael, and Raymond J. Kopp. 1990. "Social Cost of Environmental Quality
Regulations: A General Equilibrium Analysis." Journal of Political Economy
98(4):853-873.

Heagle, A.S., S. Spencer, and M.B. Letchworth. 1979. "Yield Response of Winter Wheat to
Chronic Doses of Ozone." Canadian Journal of Botany 57:(l):999-2005.

Heck, W.W., O.C. Taylor, R. Adams, G. Bingham, J. Miller, E. Preston, and L. Weinstein.

1982. "Assessment of Crop Loss from Ozone." Journal of the Air Pollution Control
Association 32(4):353-361.

Hedges, Larry V., and Ingram Olkin. 1985. Statistical Methods for Meta-Analysis. New
York: Academic Press, Inc.

Hoover's Company Information, [on-line] .

Hoover's Inc. Hoover's Online: The Ultimate Source for Company Information.
.

R-4


-------
References

Industrial Economics (IEc), Inc. 1997. Handbook for Non-Cancer Valuation: Draft.

Prepared for the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. Cambridge, MA: Industrial
Economics, Inc.

Information Access Corporation. 1997. Business & Company Profile ASAP, [computer file]
Foster City, CA: Information Access Corporation.

Intriligator, Michael D. 1978. Econometric Models, Techniques, and Applications.
Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

IRS web site. 1998. . 1998.

Just, Richard E., Darrell L. Hueth, and Andrew Schmitz. 1982. Applied Welfare Economics
and Public Policy. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc.

Katzen, Sally. Memorandum for the Heads of Executive Departments and Agencies:

Guidance for Implementing Title II of S.l. Executive Office of the President, Office
of Management and Budget, Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs. March 31,
1995.

Keller, Theodor. 1985. "S02 Effects on Tree Growth." In Sulfur Dioxide and Vegetation,
William E. Winner, Harold A. Mooney, and Robert A. Goldstein, eds., pp. 250-263.
Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

Kennedy, Peter. 1994. A Guide to Econometrics. 3rd Ed. Cambridge: MIT Press.

Kir k-Othmer Encyclopedia of Chemical Technology. 4th Ed. Serial. New York: John
Wiley & Sons.

Kolb, Jeffrey A., and Joel D. Scheraga. 1990. "Discounting the Benefits and Costs of
Environmental Regulations." Journal of Policy Analysis and Management
9:381-390.

Kopp, Raymond J. 1992. "Why Existence Values Should be Used in Cost-Benefit Analysis."
Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 11(1): 123-130.

R-5


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Kopp, R.J., W.J. Vaughan, and M. Hazilla. 1984. "Agricultural Sector Benefits Analysis for
Ozone: Methods Evaluation and Demonstration." Prepared for the U.S.
Environmental Protection Agency, Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards,
Research Triangle Park, NC.

Krutilla, K. 1967. "Conservation Reconsidered." American Economic Review 57:777-786.

Leung, S.K., W. Reed, and S. Geng. 1982. "Estimations of Ozone Damage to Selected
Crops Grown in Southern California." Journal of the Air Pollution Control
Association 32(2): 160-164.

Lind, Robert C. 1990. "Reassessing the Government's Discount Rate Policy in Light of New
Theory and Data in a World Economy with a High Degree of Capital Mobility."
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 18(2):S8-S28.

Martin, Sheila A. and H. Spencer Banzhaf. May 1994. An Assessment of Potential Damage
Costs for NSP, Draft Volume 2: Agricultural Damages Caused by Air Pollution.
Research Triangle Park, NC: Research Triangle Institute.

Mathtech, Inc. September 23, 1988. Review of Economic Impact Methodology Applied to
TSCA Section 4 Test Rules. Prepared under EPA Contract No. 68-02-4235.

Maxwell, Nan L. 1989. "Labor Market Effects from Involuntary Job Losses in Layoffs, Plant
Closings: the Role of Human Capital in Facilitating Reemployment and Reduced
Wage Losses." American Journal of Economics and Sociology 48(2):129-141.

McRAE's Blue Book Directory. 103rd Ed. 1996. New York: BRP Publications Inc.

Mendelsohn, Robert, Daniel Hellerstein, Michael Huguenin, Robert Unsworth, and Richard
Brazee. 1992. "Measuring Hazardous Waste Damage with Panel Models." Journal
of Environmental Economics and Management 22:259-271.

Miller, Gay Y., Joseph M. Rosenblatt, and Leroy J. Hushak. 1988. "The Effects of Supply
Shifts on Producers' Surplus." American Journal of Agricultural Economics
70(4):886-891.

Montgomery, Mark, and Michael Needelman. 1997. "The Welfare Effects of Toxic
Contamination in Freshwater Fish." Land Economics 73(2):211-223.

R-6


-------
References

National Environmental Information Service. The Chemical Industry Homepage.
.

National Trade and Professional Associations of the United States. 32nd Ed. 1997.
Washington, DC: Columbia Books, Inc.

New York Public Library. "How to Find U.S. Company Information." [on-line]


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

Research Triangle Institute. June 1992. Economic Analysis of Air Pollution Regulations:
By-Product Coke Ovens. Prepared for the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency,
Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards. Research Triangle Park, NC: Research
Triangle Institute.

Research Triangle Institute. August 1996a. Economic Analysis of Air Pollution Regulations:
Portland Cement Manufacturing. Prepared for the U.S. Environmental Protection
Agency, Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards. Research Triangle Park, NC:
Research Triangle Institute.

Research Triangle Institute. August 1996b. Economic Impact Analysis and Regulatory
Flexibility Analysis of the Proposed MACT Standardfor Pharmaceutical
Manufacturing. Prepared for the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Office of
Air Quality Planning and Standards. Research Triangle Park, NC: Research Triangle
Institute.

Research Triangle Institute. 1997. Economic Analysis of Pollution Regulations:

Agricultural Chemicals. Prepared for the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency,
Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards. Research Triangle Park, NC: Research
Triangle Institute.

Riley, Gwen J., John L. Warren, and Eun-Sook Goidel. "Assessment of Changes in Reported
TRI Releases and Transfers Between 1989 and 1990." Air and Waste 44:769-772.

Robert Morris Associates. Annual. Annual Statement Studies. Philadelphia, PA: Robert
Morris Associates.

Robert Morris Associates. Various years. Annual Statement Studies, [on-line]
.

Rowe, R.D., and L.G. Chestnut. 1985. "Economic Assessment of the Effects of Air
Pollution on Agricultural Crops in the San Joaquin Valley." Journal of the Air
Pollution Control Association 35:728-734.

Salter, W.E.G., and W.B. Reddaway. 1969. Productivity and Technical Change.

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Scheraga, J.D. 1989. Supplemental Guidelines on Discounting in the Preparation of
Regulatory Impact Analyses.

R-8


-------
References

Scherer, F.M. 1980. Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance. 2nd ed.
Chicago: Rand-McNally. p. 61.

Schwartz, Joel. 1993. "Particulate Air Pollution and Chronic Respiratory Disease."
Environmental Research 62:7-13.

Standard & Poor's Corporation. 1997. [CD-ROM] Palo Alto, CA: Dialog Information
Services.

Standard & Poor's Corporation. COMPUSTAT North American and Global Databases.
[computer files] [subscription] [on-line] .

Standard & Poor's Corporation. Various years. Standard & Poor's Research Reports. New
York: McGraw-Hill.

Stigler, George J. 1955. "Introduction," in Business Concentration and Price Policy,

National Bureau of Economic Research. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press,
p. 4.

The Harris Manufacturers Database, [on-line] .

Note: Fee-based service.

Thomas Register of Manufacturers, [on-line] .

Topel, Robert H. 1984. "Equilibrium Earnings, Turnover, and Unemployment: New
Evidence." Journal of Labor Economics 2(4):500-522.

Troy, Leo. Annual. Almanac of Business and Industrial Financial Ratios. Englewood
Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

Tufte, Edward R. 1997. Visual Explanations. Cheshire, CT: Graphics Press.

Ullman 's Encyclopedia of Industry Chemistry. 6th Ed. 1998. New York: John Wiley &
Sons.

U.S. Bureau of Census. PDF Publications Index, .

R-9


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

U.S. Bureau of the Census. 1995. County Government Finances: 1991-1992, Series GF/92-
8. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office.

U.S. Bureau of the Census. 1996. Characteristics of Business Owners Database, [computer
file] .

U.S. Bureau of the Census. 1996. City Government Finances: 1991-1992, Series GF/92-4.
Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office.

U.S. Bureau of the Census. 1996. Government Finances: 1991-1992, Series GF/92-5.
Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office.

U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis. 1997. Regional Economic Information System: 1969-
1996. [computer file], . Washington,
DC: U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis.

U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. BLS LABSTAT Database, 

U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics/U.S. Bureau of Census. 1996. Current Population Survey.
[computer file], . Updated March 11,
1996.

U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. Annual Survey of Manufactures.
Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, [on-line] .

U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. Finances of Federal, State, and Local
Governments (includingschools). [on-line] .

U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Data Services Division. Various
years. Economic Census. [CD-ROM] Washington, DC.

U.S. Department of Commerce. Quarterly Financial Report for Manufacturing, Mining, and
Trade Corporations. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.

U.S. Department of Commerce. 1992 Census of Government Titles, [computer file],
.

R-10


-------
References

U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1995. 1992 Census of Governments.
[on-line] .

U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 1995. 1992 Census of Manufactures:
Industry Series, [on-line] .

U.S. Department of Commerce. 1997. 1992 Census of Governments. Volume 3, Public

Government, Number 2, Compendium of Public Employment. Washington, DC: U.S

U.S. Department of Commerce. 1997. 1992 Census of Governments. Volume 4,

Government finances, Number 5, Compendium of Government Finances. Washington,
DC: U.S Department of Commerce. Department of Commerce.

U.S. Department of Commerce. 1998. County and City Business Patterns.

<. Updated December 17.

U.S Department of Commerce. 1999. Map Stats, [computer file],

. Obtained March 29, 1999.

U.S. Department of Energy. 1992. U.S. National Acid Precipitation Assessment Program:
Report to Congress. Washington, DC. Prepared by Roger Morris.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. August 1991. RIB How-To Guide: Use and
Substitutes Reports. Washington, DC.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. March 1993. Regulatory Impact Analysis for the
Final Rulemaking on Corrective Action for Solid Waste Management Units:

Proposed Methodology for Analysis. Washington, DC: Office of Solid Waste.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. April 1995a. The Environmental Protection

Agency's Environmental Justice Strategy. Washington, DC: Office of Environmental
Justice.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. March 1995b. Interim Guidance on the Unfunded
Mandates Reform Act of 1995. Washington, DC: Office of General Counsel.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. May 1996a. The Benefits and Costs of the Clean
Air Act, 1970 to 1990. Prepared for the U.S. Congress. Washington, DC: U.S.
Environmental Protection Agency.

R-ll


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 1996b. TSCA Title IV, Sections 402(a) and 404:
Target Housing and Child-Occupied Facilities, Final Rule: Regulatory Impact
Analysis. Washington, DC: Office of Pollution Prevention and Toxics, Regulatory
Impacts Branch.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. November 1997a. "Benefits-Transfer Analysis for
Pulp and Paper." OAQPS Staff Paper. Research Triangle Park, NC: OAQPS.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 1997b. Cost of Illness Handbook. Washington, DC:
Office of Pollution Prevention and Toxics, Economics Exposure and Technology
Division, Regulatory Impacts Branch.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. April 1997c. Economic Analysis of the Final Rule
to Add Certain Industry Groups to EPCRA Section 313. Washington, DC: Office of
Pollution Prevention and Toxics.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. September 2, 1997d. Economic Assessment for the
Amended Proposed TSCA Section 4(a) Test Rule for 21 Hazardous Air Pollutants.
Washington, DC: Economics, Exposure and Technology Division.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. February 5, 1997e. Engineering Inputs for the
Economic Impact Analysis. Research Triangle Park, NC: Office of Air Quality
Planning and Standards.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. February 5, 1997f. EPA Interim Guidance for

Implementing the Small Business Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act and Related
Provisions of the Regulatory Flexibility Act. Washington, DC: EPA SBREFA Task
Force.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. May 1997g. Evaluating the Equity of

Environmental Policy Options Based on the Distribution of Economic Effects:
Preliminary Draft. Washington, DC: Office of Policy, Planning, and Evaluation.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. September 30, 1997h. Interim Guidance for
Incorporating Environmental Justice Concerns in EPA 's NEPA Compliance
Analyses. Washington, DC: Office of Federal Activities.

R-12


-------
References

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. April 21, 1997i. Selecting Baselines in Agency

Economic Analysis. Prepared for the Regulatory Policy Council. Washington, DC:
Economic Consistency Workgroup.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. February 25, 1997j. Treatment of Discounting and
Intergenerational Issues in Benefit-Cost Analysis. Prepared for the Regulatory Policy
Council. Washington, DC: Economic Consistency Workgroup.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. March 25, 1998a. Economic Impact Analysis and
Small Entity Impact Analysis of Proposed TSCA Section 4(a) Test Rule for
48 Chemicals Targetedfor Dermal Absorption Testing. Washington, DC:

Economics, Exposure and Technology Division.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. July 1998b. Economic Impact and Regulatory

Flexibility Analyses of the Final Architectural Coatings VOC Rule. Washington, DC:
Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. September 1998c. Guidance on the Preparation of
Economic Analyses in OPPT. Washington, DC: Office of Pollution Prevention and
Toxics, Economic Analysis and Policy Branch.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. July 1998d. Guidelines for Preparing Economic
Analyses. Preliminary draft report. Washington, DC: Office of Policy, Planning, and
Evaluation.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 1998e. ICR Handbook: EPA's Guide to Writing
Information Collection Requests Under the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995.
Washington, DC: Office of Policy, Planning, and Evaluation, Regulatory Information
Division.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. Facility Information Data System (FINDS)

Database [computer file]. Includes Dun & Bradstreet's DUNS Market Identifiers
database. .

U.S. Geological Survey. Minerals Information: Publications and Data Products.
.

U.S. International Trade Administration. Various years. U.S. Industry and Trade Outlook,
formerly U.S. Industrial Outlook. New York: McGraw-Hill.

R-13


-------
OAQPS Economic Analysis Resource Document

U.S. International Trade Commission. 1994. Synthetic Organic Chemicals: U.S. Production
and Sales. Washington, DC: U.S. International Trade Commission.

U.S. International Trade Commission. U.S. ITC Trade Data Web .

U.S. Manufacturers Database [computer file], Harris Information Sources.
.

U.S. National Acid Precipitation Assessment Program. June 1993. 1992 Report to Congress.

U.S. Security and Exchange Commission. EDGAR Database, [on-line] .

U.S. Small Business Administration. Firm Size Data Provided by the Bureau of the Census,
[on-line] .

United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Development. 1985 to present (annual).
International Trade Statistics Yearbook. New York: United Nations.

Value Line Investment Survey. New York: Value Line Publishing.

Value Line Publishing, Inc. Various years. Value Line Reports, [on-line] .

Van Houtven, George, and Maureen L. Cropper. 1996. "When is a Life Too Costly to Save?
The Evidence from U.S. Environmental Regulations." Journal of Environmental
Economics and Management 30:348-368.

Viscusi, W. Kip, John M. Vernon, and Joseph E. Harrington, Jr. 1992. Economics of
Regulation and Antitrust. Lexington, MA: D.C. Heath and Company.

Wall Street Research Network, [on-line] .

Wesley, A. Magat, Alan J. Krupnick, and Winston Harrington. 1986. Rules in the Making:
A Statistical Analysis of Regulatory Agency Behavior. Washington, DC: Resources
for the Future.

World Scope, [computer file] Bethesda, MD: Disclosure Incorporated.

Yahoo! Yahoo! Finance, .

R-14


-------